26.07.2013 Views

RTA and Economic Growth. The case of SADC - DAAD partnership ...

RTA and Economic Growth. The case of SADC - DAAD partnership ...

RTA and Economic Growth. The case of SADC - DAAD partnership ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Abstract<br />

<strong>RTA</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Growth</strong>.<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>case</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong><br />

B Seetanah<br />

<strong>The</strong> research analyses the relationship between <strong>SADC</strong> <strong>RTA</strong> <strong>and</strong> growth for the period 1995-2008.<br />

R<strong>and</strong>om effect estimates shows that <strong>SADC</strong> trade has been growth inductive but relative less as<br />

compared to no <strong>SADC</strong> trade. <strong>The</strong> results are confirmed using GMM panel estimates. <strong>The</strong> relatively<br />

low contribution is in line with the statistics <strong>and</strong> highlighted that trade within <strong>SADC</strong> is still relatively<br />

low. Trade to NON<strong>SADC</strong> countries is observed to have been very influential to the economic<br />

development <strong>of</strong> the countries in the sample. Further analysis pertaining to the <strong>case</strong> <strong>of</strong> Mauritius<br />

revealed that <strong>SADC</strong> trade had a relatively small output elasticity as compared to NON <strong>SADC</strong> trade<br />

confirming that trade to the other non <strong>SADC</strong> partners, especially EU, is more influential in<br />

explaining the Mauritian economic growth.<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

Countries have been vigorously implementing <strong>RTA</strong>s as a central objective <strong>of</strong> their trade policy<br />

(Brown, 2005). <strong>The</strong> wave <strong>of</strong> regionalism spread most visibly <strong>and</strong> it did not only alter the regional<br />

economic relations between member countries but also highlighted the relative importance <strong>of</strong><br />

regionalism on a global scenario. It is noteworthy that Venables (1999) argues that regional<br />

agreements between developing countries have been mostly related with divergence <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

performance.<br />

Regional trade agreement is a key strategy that is enabling countries to accelerate the expansion <strong>of</strong><br />

markets, widen the region’s economic space, <strong>and</strong> finally maximizing the welfare <strong>of</strong> the member<br />

states. A prevalent global trend towards Regional trade agreements (<strong>RTA</strong>s) has been noted since the<br />

early 1990s <strong>and</strong> from then it is still burgeoning. Presently, 157 members were recorded in the<br />

organization. Figure 1 shows the evolution <strong>of</strong> the average number <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong> partners for the current<br />

member <strong>of</strong> WTO.


Figure 1 - Average Number <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong> Partners over Time - Source from WTO<br />

<strong>The</strong> different types <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s are shown above in the diagram. FTA st<strong>and</strong>s for Free trade<br />

agreements, FTA & EIA st<strong>and</strong>s for Free trade agreement <strong>and</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Integration Agreement, CU<br />

st<strong>and</strong>s for custom unions, CU & EIA st<strong>and</strong>s for custom unions <strong>and</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Integration<br />

Agreement, PSA & EIA st<strong>and</strong>s for property settlement agreement <strong>and</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Integration<br />

Agreement, EIA st<strong>and</strong>s for <strong>Economic</strong> Integration Agreement <strong>and</strong> PSA only st<strong>and</strong>s for property<br />

settlement agreement.<br />

<strong>The</strong> different agreements in WTO vary in duties towards its member states. One may be for<br />

promoting agricultural trade amongst trade while another one is to make sure balance between<br />

countries consumption <strong>and</strong> productions are met. WTO experienced increase in membership <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>RTA</strong>s members every year. <strong>The</strong> reason for this increasing trend is the gains from increased openness<br />

to trade are from resources which are productively allocated <strong>and</strong> thereby decrease cost, leading to a<br />

lowering in consumer prices. <strong>The</strong> different <strong>RTA</strong>s in force in WTO are shown above in the diagram.<br />

However, the welfare that can be earned is not guaranteed. <strong>The</strong> benefits are subject to costs <strong>and</strong><br />

externalities which may nullify the gains. Furthermore the trend may lead to damaging long-run<br />

effects on external trade liberalization. <strong>The</strong> most popular issue about <strong>RTA</strong>s is discriminations <strong>and</strong><br />

the potential for trade diversion.<br />

Regional Corporations behaves as a channel through which surplus national production can be<br />

exchanged to the products <strong>of</strong> other countries. <strong>The</strong> consensus is that trade promotes growth <strong>and</strong>


educes poverty. <strong>RTA</strong>s can nevertheless fail <strong>and</strong> that in multiple facets. <strong>The</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s on an<br />

economy is thus not conclusive.<br />

This study aims to answer questions on whether <strong>RTA</strong> is growth conducive. In the first instance the<br />

study is performed on a sample <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> member states using both static <strong>and</strong> dynamic panel data<br />

framework. <strong>The</strong> study goes further in focusing the potential growth effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> on the<br />

Mauritian <strong>case</strong> study. <strong>The</strong> latter is performed by employing a dynamic time series approach, namely<br />

a Vector Autoregression framework which account for dynamism <strong>and</strong> endogeneity. <strong>The</strong> above<br />

analysis requires in the first instance a decomposition <strong>of</strong> trade into <strong>SADC</strong> <strong>and</strong> non <strong>SADC</strong> so as to<br />

have interesting comparative relative insights.<br />

LITERATURE REVIEW<br />

<strong>The</strong>oretical review<br />

Trade encourages the allocation <strong>of</strong> resources based on the perceived comparative advantage <strong>of</strong><br />

participating countries <strong>and</strong> derive significant gains from trading. <strong>The</strong> theory that trade is positively<br />

correlated with economic growth goes back to Adam Smith, who greatly favoured specialization.<br />

With regional agreements, trade certainly bolsters up, but there are no guarantees that the aggregate<br />

benefits are distributed equitably among the trading partners. <strong>The</strong>re are winners <strong>and</strong> losers in trading<br />

relationship. What is to be taken into consideration, thus, is the degree <strong>of</strong> gain from trade. Some<br />

factors that determine the degree <strong>of</strong> gain are; the terms <strong>of</strong> trade, exchange rate <strong>and</strong> market<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> the countries. On that, Baldwin (2003) demonstrated that countries with less trade<br />

restrictions achieve more rapidly economic growth. Trade liberalisation reduces relative price<br />

distortions <strong>and</strong> allows those activities with a comparative advantage to exp<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> hence promotes<br />

economic growth.<br />

According to Yeats (1998), negativity in economic terms, comprise <strong>of</strong> trade diversion, reduction <strong>of</strong><br />

quality, increasing consumer prices <strong>and</strong> even lowering the global competitiveness <strong>of</strong> a country.<br />

Moreover, investment, economic growth, government tax revenue <strong>and</strong> employment may also drop.<br />

Extent <strong>of</strong> effects may fall, <strong>and</strong> wealth <strong>and</strong> income distribution <strong>and</strong> living st<strong>and</strong>ards may fall; stated<br />

Woodcock (2001) to social relations. In political domain, stability <strong>and</strong> cooperation may be on<br />

decline, <strong>and</strong> conflicts on the rise (World Bank, 2000). Barbier (2003) specified that sustainable<br />

development may not always complement economic expansion. In terms <strong>of</strong> culture <strong>of</strong> a country,<br />

unique identity <strong>and</strong> unity <strong>of</strong> a country may be lost; this is more acute among smaller countries


ecause <strong>of</strong> the imposition <strong>of</strong> larger countries culture; which may result in st<strong>and</strong>ardization <strong>of</strong> culture<br />

among member states.<br />

Application <strong>of</strong> regional integrations in the world has been a puzzling issue over time. Regional<br />

integration has been encouraged to make good relationship based on regional stability <strong>and</strong><br />

development, hence aiming at optimising revenues at fewer risks. <strong>The</strong> formation <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s is driven<br />

by a number <strong>of</strong> factors, including economic, political <strong>and</strong> security considerations. Membership to<br />

integration is a choice which may be driven by motives like; gaining access to large markets, new<br />

customers, competitive shoots, benefiting from MFN tariffs, enhancing investments, promoting the<br />

environment <strong>and</strong> labour st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> so on. <strong>The</strong>se integrations vary widely in structure, objectives,<br />

sector coverage <strong>and</strong> membership. As mentioned earlier, integration envelops developing countries<br />

amongst other staged countries. To that, Whalley (1996) argued that regionalism could serve as an<br />

elite-socialization process <strong>and</strong> as a lock-in mechanism for domestic political <strong>and</strong> economic reforms<br />

in less developed <strong>RTA</strong> members.<br />

In the past decades, many authors explored integration agreements <strong>and</strong> concluded that global<br />

economic integration is the vital to promoting resource allocation, technology transfer <strong>and</strong><br />

augmenting the st<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>of</strong> living, hence growth. Some studies have added-on that economic<br />

integration led to trade imbalances, increased financial market volatility <strong>and</strong> nurtured less-effective<br />

macroeconomic policies. Definitive conclusions have yet to be drawn. Moreover, Michael Mussa,<br />

the former director <strong>of</strong> research at the International Monetary Fund (IMF) found three fundamental<br />

factors that affect the process <strong>of</strong> economic integration, namely technology, preferences <strong>and</strong> public<br />

policy. Increased technology has assisted economic integration by lowering the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

transportation <strong>and</strong> also reduced the cost <strong>of</strong> communication. Public policies depending on a<br />

country’s objectives may promote or even hinder economic integration. Although the factors<br />

independently influence integration, causality between them is present.<br />

In theory <strong>and</strong> complementing statement <strong>of</strong> Balassa (1965) <strong>and</strong> DeRosa (1992), <strong>RTA</strong>s accomplish<br />

common objectives that encourage economic transformations in trade, customs union, common<br />

market economic union amongst others. Combination <strong>of</strong> regional, sub-regional <strong>and</strong> multilateral<br />

negotiations enabled government to be in a more open environment for cross border economic<br />

transactions. Government seek to enforce regional security <strong>and</strong> peace with member states <strong>and</strong> may<br />

even try to increase power in their negotiations, by first securitizing their governance commitment


ased on political <strong>and</strong> economic reforms. <strong>The</strong>y may even create <strong>and</strong> use political alliances, in the<br />

foreground, to be prejudiced.<br />

Some researchers argue that <strong>RTA</strong>s is an obstacle to multilateralism <strong>and</strong> globalisation. Countries are<br />

favouring <strong>RTA</strong>s over multilateral trade objectives in their trade policy; as their belief is that gain is<br />

higher with <strong>RTA</strong>s. However the effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s is not a basic thing which can be applied to<br />

everything. According to the Global <strong>Economic</strong> Prospects (2005), the result <strong>of</strong> an agreement on<br />

trade depends on their design <strong>and</strong> implementation. <strong>The</strong> most important thing in <strong>RTA</strong>s is the extent<br />

the trade barriers are lowered. Brown (2005) complemented the success <strong>of</strong> regional integration,<br />

which lies upon several factors, namely, domestic security, political <strong>and</strong> civic commitment, mutual<br />

trust, macro-economic stability, good financial management <strong>and</strong> expansive national reforms.<br />

<strong>The</strong>refore, prosperous regional integrations shall complement <strong>and</strong> not hinder multilateral<br />

negotiations. <strong>The</strong> aims for <strong>and</strong> welfares <strong>of</strong> forming <strong>RTA</strong>s have greatly been defined in general<br />

context.<br />

Frankel (1997) identified a number <strong>of</strong> traditional gains from trade; enforcing <strong>of</strong> domestic policy,<br />

guarantees <strong>of</strong> market access, increased multilateral power, <strong>and</strong> tactical bonds to multilateral <strong>and</strong><br />

regional relationships. Other benefits defined by Fern<strong>and</strong>ez (1997) are the increase in credibility,<br />

signaling, insurance, <strong>and</strong> coordination amongst countries. Reasons other than benefits are also<br />

prevalent. Firstly, the reaction to forming <strong>RTA</strong>s may be because <strong>of</strong> impatience towards the slow<br />

process <strong>and</strong> progress <strong>of</strong> multilateral approaches like, Doha Round. Secondly, the ‘b<strong>and</strong>wagon effect’<br />

can be one <strong>of</strong> the causes <strong>of</strong> development <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s. This effect was proposed by Bhagwati (1993)<br />

<strong>and</strong> is about small countries joining an agreement to follow policies <strong>of</strong> larger countries to make up<br />

on market. Another reason is that cooperation has increased not be globally left out.<br />

At this instant, address will be on the objectives <strong>of</strong> a regional integration. A few to mention here are<br />

intra REC 1 trade, free movement <strong>of</strong> persons, goods <strong>and</strong> services, macroeconomic policy<br />

convergence, physical integration, sectoral integration <strong>and</strong> cross cutting issues.<br />

1 Regional economic activities


Figure 2.<br />

A diagram (Figure 2.) was set to up to illustrate the objectives that <strong>RTA</strong>s try to achieve, discussed<br />

below <strong>and</strong> which results in cropping up <strong>of</strong> gains from trade in the region.<br />

<strong>The</strong> first one to be considered here is Intra REC trade. Countries generally enter <strong>RTA</strong>s to increase<br />

trade amongst member states. Countries have traded in accordance to a pattern with outside<br />

countries other than countries in their own continent. African countries, for example, prefer to trade<br />

with countries outside its continent rather than among themselves.<br />

Secondly the freedom <strong>of</strong> movement; the freedom <strong>of</strong> commodities, capital <strong>and</strong> people is necessary<br />

for successful integration. However, this process is quite troublesome but countries which adopted it<br />

prospered compared to the others. Freedom <strong>of</strong> people includes people may travel without visa or<br />

easily obtain visa to travel in members countries, rights <strong>of</strong> establishments <strong>and</strong> residence, shared laws<br />

<strong>and</strong> media <strong>and</strong> so forth. Other incentives include harmonizing customs procedures <strong>and</strong> instruments,<br />

adopting common tariffs procedures <strong>and</strong> creating a single administrative document.<br />

Macroeconomic policy convergence is implementing a stable economy on which member states may<br />

rely for trade. This is concerned with stabilising the factors which affect the economy such as;<br />

inflation, interest rates, level <strong>of</strong> employment among others. Thus, the aim is to engage in prudent<br />

macroeconomic policies to enhance economic growth <strong>and</strong> gain from sustainable development which


further results in the promotion <strong>of</strong> trade flows. <strong>The</strong>se factors will vary from economies to<br />

economies because their targets <strong>and</strong> objectives might not be similar.<br />

Physical integration is mainly about infrastructure which greatly impact on exploitation <strong>of</strong> local<br />

resources, transfer <strong>of</strong> information <strong>and</strong> use <strong>of</strong> communication technologies. Operational<br />

infrastructures are thus required to aid trade.<br />

Sectoral integration is also important. For example an agriculture based economy is open to drought,<br />

floods <strong>and</strong> even pests. By engaging in an integration, projects such as ensuring the security <strong>of</strong> the<br />

REC‘s food supply, the country is less vulnerable to problems like famine. Another <strong>case</strong> is where<br />

integration cares for industries. Increase in productivity <strong>and</strong> competitiveness <strong>of</strong> countries in <strong>RTA</strong>s<br />

were noted. Some reasons are movement <strong>of</strong> labour, special protocols applied to member states only<br />

<strong>and</strong> so on.<br />

<strong>The</strong> last one is cross cutting issues. This one is divided into three for clearer underst<strong>and</strong>ing. <strong>The</strong> first<br />

one is private sector. With integration, an economy is forced to gather all together to work as best as<br />

possible. For example, private <strong>and</strong> public sector have to settle arrangements on certain terms, hence<br />

enforcing the political <strong>and</strong> economic stability in a country. <strong>The</strong> second one is peace <strong>and</strong> security. A<br />

country will dress the image <strong>of</strong> itself in front <strong>of</strong> the member states; hence it will create a suitable<br />

environment for trade. This leads to friendly ties in trade <strong>and</strong> stability in the country. <strong>The</strong> last one is<br />

socio-economic issues. That is, in an <strong>RTA</strong>, issues like violence, discriminations amongst others are<br />

cared <strong>of</strong>.<br />

Despite the challenges in the process <strong>of</strong> an <strong>RTA</strong>, significant progress will be noted if a country is a<br />

member in an <strong>RTA</strong>, hence member states must consider regional integration in their strategic<br />

development projects.<br />

<strong>RTA</strong>s can nevertheless fail <strong>and</strong> that in multiple facets. <strong>The</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s on an economy is thus<br />

not conclusive. This study aims to answer questions on whether there is trade amelioration when<br />

before <strong>and</strong> being member in an <strong>RTA</strong>. This paper focuses on <strong>SADC</strong>’s member states’ trade with<br />

Mauritius. For a more concise analysis <strong>of</strong> benefits from trade for a later section in the paper, trade<br />

creation <strong>and</strong> trade diversion are explained below.<br />

Trade Creation <strong>and</strong> Trade Diversion


Viner (1950) theory postulates assessment <strong>of</strong> welfare effect from an <strong>RTA</strong> with the explanation <strong>of</strong><br />

trade creation, trade diversion <strong>and</strong> revenue effect. For the purpose <strong>of</strong> this paper, only trade creation<br />

<strong>and</strong> trade diversion are considered.<br />

Trade creation occurs when the implementation <strong>of</strong> an <strong>RTA</strong> in a country leave supply come from<br />

more efficient producers <strong>of</strong> products. Trade creation outcome, in theory, is said to be the add value<br />

in welfare. In other words, it happens when consumers enjoys imported goods at lower prices as a<br />

result <strong>of</strong> fall in price from the elimination <strong>of</strong> tariffs in the free trade area. <strong>The</strong> fact that prices are<br />

reduced, hence lower cost, more consumers enter the market as they can now afford to buy goods<br />

<strong>of</strong> higher quality. Trade creation therefore occurs as low cost member countries displace high cost<br />

domestic producers. Hence, it can be said that a positive consumption effect that benefits<br />

consumers <strong>of</strong> member countries is present.<br />

Trade diversion on the other h<strong>and</strong>, means that potentially better efficient producers outside the<br />

<strong>RTA</strong> are no more the ones supplying a country; as the country has shifted its supply or provision <strong>of</strong><br />

goods towards a less efficient producer within the <strong>RTA</strong>. Lee (2008) stated that regionalism has the<br />

potential <strong>of</strong> diverting bilateral trade away from countries outside the bloc; hence trade diversion.<br />

This process may lead to the shift <strong>of</strong> production from low cost to high cost producers; welfare loss.<br />

<strong>The</strong> consumer now incurs higher cost for the same goods.<br />

Presence <strong>of</strong> both trade creation <strong>and</strong> trade diversion in a free trade agreement implies that member<br />

countries experience both positive <strong>and</strong> negative impacts. Assessment <strong>of</strong> an <strong>RTA</strong> should be based on<br />

the net effect <strong>of</strong> the two, which will determine whether there is a welfare gain or loss. Implementing<br />

very low external tariffs (open regionalism arrangements) could help to lessen the risk <strong>of</strong> trade<br />

diversion. <strong>RTA</strong>s may cause changes in the world welfare depending on the relative degree <strong>of</strong> trade<br />

creation <strong>and</strong> trade diversion effects.<br />

In addition to that, <strong>RTA</strong> impact on welfare can be categorized into two types; static effects <strong>and</strong><br />

dynamic effects. Both effects usually result in a gain when there is a reduction in costs, increase in<br />

bargaining power, investment incentives in countries due to decrease in tariffs amongst others. Static<br />

effects are ways to gain when the country takes advantage <strong>of</strong> differences in factor endowments,<br />

market power <strong>and</strong> their availability <strong>of</strong> technologies. It is similar to arbitrage theory <strong>and</strong> the countries<br />

may generate gain from economies <strong>of</strong> scale, efforts towards product differentiation <strong>and</strong> constantly<br />

innovating products. <strong>The</strong> dynamic effects usually broken further into two types, namely;


competition effects <strong>and</strong> scale effects, dem<strong>and</strong>s more efforts for gains. Many researchers state that<br />

dynamic effects are the incentive to join in <strong>RTA</strong>s. <strong>The</strong>se effects comprise <strong>of</strong> higher production<br />

efficiency resulting from decrease in average production costs because <strong>of</strong> increased competition. <strong>The</strong><br />

countries are forced to decrease cost via for example economies <strong>of</strong> scale. Other dynamic methods to<br />

gains are increase international investment by increasing investment opportunities, exp<strong>and</strong> market<br />

scale, constantly improving technology in production.<br />

A country open to trade is forced to continuously innovate to remain competitive. Increased<br />

economic integration with the outside world adds to technological innovation through trade <strong>of</strong><br />

technologies from developed countries, like Japan. Krugman (2003) stated that once poor countries<br />

made their way to a better economy with globalisation.<br />

Empirical review<br />

Grossman <strong>and</strong> Helpman (1994) showed that integration with the world economy can boost a<br />

country’s productivity. Productivity <strong>and</strong> economic growth through integration or trade applies to<br />

developing countries as well as industrial countries. <strong>The</strong> two largest poverty stricken populations,<br />

China <strong>and</strong> India, have achieved productivity <strong>and</strong> economic growth during the last two decades with<br />

open trade. Thus, theory matches actual trends <strong>and</strong> results. <strong>The</strong> connection between trade <strong>and</strong><br />

growth is said to be positively correlated, but reducing trade barriers do not always have nice impact.<br />

Scitovski <strong>and</strong> Scott (1970) <strong>and</strong> Balassa (1971) were first to address this negativity. However, studies<br />

like; Dollar (1992), Sachs <strong>and</strong> Warner (1995) <strong>and</strong> Ben-David (1993) persists on positive correlations<br />

between a country’s openness <strong>and</strong> faster economic growth.<br />

Both before <strong>and</strong> after engaging in regional corporations, are liable to praises <strong>and</strong> critics. Different<br />

studies brought different results. Jacob Viner (1950) is the first one who considered analysis on trade<br />

patterns with regional blocs <strong>and</strong> his conclusion was that benefits or gains from <strong>RTA</strong>s are dependent<br />

upon trade creation <strong>and</strong> trade diversion. Furthermore, Johnson (1960) explained that welfare from<br />

trade creation <strong>and</strong> diversion may leave the country better or worse <strong>of</strong>f. Both sides are probable<br />

which he explained from a partial equilibrium diagram illustrating the economic effects, good <strong>and</strong><br />

bad.<br />

<strong>The</strong> most common tests carried on Regional Trade effects on countries is the Gravity model. It was<br />

proposed by Tinbergen (1962) to explain international bilateral trade <strong>and</strong> used it to determine the<br />

factors affecting trade patterns. Aitken (1973) used that same model for analysis on <strong>RTA</strong>s. Most


esearchers who used the model have ended saying that <strong>RTA</strong>s are trade creating. <strong>The</strong> extent <strong>of</strong><br />

welfare gained by member states depend on certain variable used in the equations <strong>and</strong> other factors<br />

which vary from countries to countries, for instance economic structure <strong>of</strong> a country. Hence, it<br />

depends on the data gathered <strong>and</strong> variable opted for in the model (Burfisher et al. (2001)).<br />

Magee (2003) had used simultaneous equations model to show empirically that with high bilateral<br />

trade, countries have their pr<strong>of</strong>itability boosted up <strong>and</strong> hence will encourage creation <strong>of</strong> agreements.<br />

Consideration was also made where increase in trade might be linked to historical <strong>and</strong> political issues<br />

amongst them <strong>and</strong> not only due to creation <strong>of</strong> corporations. Bayoumi <strong>and</strong> Eichengreen (1995)<br />

confirmed the above results.<br />

Not only the data <strong>and</strong> variables that are dealt with, but the sample <strong>of</strong> countries chosen also,<br />

determined the extent <strong>of</strong> accuracy in results. Pomfret (1997) have exposed a variety <strong>of</strong> conclusions<br />

upon trade effects using the gravity model <strong>and</strong> left with no flow, hence inadequacy in the model<br />

approach. Haveman <strong>and</strong> Hummels (1998) accorded that conclusions on the predictions <strong>of</strong> trade <strong>and</strong><br />

the effects <strong>of</strong> trade, with or without regional corporations, vary greatly with sample differences. In<br />

addition, Ghosh <strong>and</strong> Yamarik (2004) approved that model results are sensitive to the variables<br />

included in the equation. <strong>The</strong>y tested the sensibility <strong>of</strong> the model by utilizing different samples <strong>and</strong><br />

found that the numbers <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s that are trade creating with a sample are not with another sample.<br />

Some important <strong>and</strong> relevant studies are discussed below.<br />

Venables (1999) tested the benefits <strong>and</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> a free trade area on member states. He used a<br />

generalized Heckscher-Ohlin model whereby assuming same level <strong>of</strong> technology prevails but with<br />

different labour types, skilled <strong>and</strong> unskilled, based on their comparative advantage. As a whole, his<br />

results showed that developing countries were more capable to exploit the free trade agreements.<br />

Soloaga <strong>and</strong> Winters (1997) argued on trade diversion existence in EU <strong>and</strong> EFTA 2 . <strong>The</strong>y used<br />

annual non-fuel data for 58 countries from 1980 to 1996 which represented around 70% <strong>of</strong> total<br />

world imports at that time. General results were that they found that the imports <strong>of</strong> both<br />

organisations were lower in 1995 to 1996 than in prior period. <strong>The</strong>y worked with three sets <strong>of</strong><br />

dummy variables for each trade bloc. <strong>The</strong>y considered intra bloc trade, one bloc recording imports<br />

by members from all countries, including nonmembers, <strong>and</strong> another one taking exports by bloc<br />

members only to all countries, including nonmembers. <strong>The</strong> first dummy represents the effect <strong>of</strong> a<br />

2 European Free Trade Association


PTA on members’ trade <strong>and</strong> the two last dummies suggest the degree <strong>of</strong> imports <strong>and</strong> exports as a<br />

whole. <strong>The</strong>y tested for changes in the trade flows before <strong>and</strong> after the implementation <strong>of</strong> blocs <strong>and</strong><br />

concluded that no great changes in intra trade were noticed. Hence, the tendency <strong>of</strong> intra- bloc trade<br />

remained nearly unchanged both before <strong>and</strong> after creation <strong>of</strong> blocs.<br />

Rahman (2006) focused on the trade diversions between developed <strong>and</strong> developing countries <strong>and</strong><br />

considered several <strong>RTA</strong>s, laying emphasis on SAFTA. He worked with the gravity model <strong>and</strong> panel<br />

data was adopted with country pair fixed effects <strong>and</strong> year specific fixed effects. He captured the time<br />

dimension <strong>and</strong> cross section specification <strong>of</strong> the data by using two-stage estimation method. <strong>The</strong><br />

conclusion was that significant intra bloc export creation was present plus also net export diversion<br />

in SAFTA.<br />

Chong Wha Lee (2008) tested the relationship or degree <strong>of</strong> relationship between trade creating <strong>and</strong><br />

trade diverting effects <strong>of</strong> some <strong>RTA</strong>s. <strong>The</strong> author used the panel data, dividing observations into<br />

five years for the period 1950 to 1999. His study arrived at distinctive results. First one being that<br />

trade creating effects were found in five (EC, CACM, MERCOSUR, ASEAN, <strong>and</strong> SPARTECA) <strong>of</strong><br />

the set <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s taken. He also arrived at concluding that trade creating effects were at a declining<br />

rate in EC, CACM, MERCOSUR, <strong>and</strong> ASEAN. He added to that, countries ignore their differences<br />

<strong>and</strong> over stated the positive effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s. <strong>The</strong> last point he made is that EU <strong>and</strong> NAFTA were<br />

quite close to trade compared to other <strong>RTA</strong>s such as ASEAN <strong>and</strong> MERCOSUR.<br />

Coulibaly (2006) laid emphasis on six developing <strong>RTA</strong>s; ECOWAS <strong>and</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> in Sub- Saharan<br />

Africa, AFTA in Asia <strong>and</strong> CACM, CAN, MERCOSUR in Latin America, <strong>and</strong> two developed <strong>RTA</strong>s;<br />

EU <strong>and</strong> NAFTA. Data as from 1960 to 1996 was taken for comparison <strong>of</strong> the positive effects <strong>and</strong><br />

trade levels between the developing <strong>and</strong> developed <strong>RTA</strong>s along the years. Gravity model combined<br />

with kernel <strong>and</strong> bootstrap estimation techniques was used. <strong>The</strong> author found that welfare impacts<br />

differed between younger <strong>and</strong> mature <strong>RTA</strong>s. He stated that AFTA, CAN, MERCOSUR, NAFTA<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> which were new at that time had positive impacts in their infant years. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, older <strong>RTA</strong>s such as CACM, ECOWAS <strong>and</strong> EU at that time have had more volatile welfare<br />

impacts. <strong>The</strong> latter added that trade <strong>and</strong> welfare impacts <strong>of</strong> both developing <strong>and</strong> developed <strong>RTA</strong>s<br />

have had no uniformed evolution.<br />

Brown (2005) discussed that agreements have an impact on economic, social <strong>and</strong> political climates<br />

<strong>of</strong> a country. He considered the EU for his study <strong>and</strong> found that imports were now cheaper <strong>and</strong><br />

exports were more pr<strong>of</strong>itable with agreements. This leads to the creation or the continuation <strong>of</strong>


foreign direct investment in a country, hereby enhancing economic growth, improve balance <strong>of</strong><br />

payments <strong>and</strong> may even bring new skills <strong>and</strong> technology.<br />

A more recent research is carried in the Western Hemisphere by Muhammad <strong>and</strong> Yucer (2010).<br />

<strong>The</strong>y studied on how the welfare effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>RTA</strong>s are dependent on trade creation <strong>and</strong> trade<br />

diversion generated. <strong>The</strong>y took 38 countries with six <strong>RTA</strong>s in the Western Hemisphere for 1986 to<br />

2005. <strong>The</strong>y used the gravity model based on Santos Silva’s <strong>and</strong> Tenreyo’s (2005) Poisson Pseudo-<br />

Maximum Likelihood (PPML) method. According to them they got more accurate results about<br />

trade impacts compared to the PPML. <strong>The</strong>ir estimates showed that trade creation was positively<br />

significant except for NAFTA <strong>and</strong> LAIA <strong>and</strong> that trade diversion effects <strong>of</strong> these two greatly varied.<br />

In addition to that, while NAFTA, LAILA <strong>and</strong> MERCOSUR had a remarkable trade diversion<br />

effect, ANDEAN <strong>and</strong> CACM had a positive significant trade diversion coefficient. After<br />

considering their analysis, conclusion is that <strong>RTA</strong>s do not only help countries to enhance their trade<br />

movements <strong>and</strong> relations between members but also improve or contribute to the world trade.<br />

<strong>SADC</strong><br />

This concept <strong>of</strong> regional integration was created with the vision <strong>of</strong> ensuring economic well-being,<br />

improvement <strong>of</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>of</strong> living <strong>and</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> life, freedom <strong>and</strong> social justice. <strong>SADC</strong> was<br />

first introduced when the Head <strong>of</strong> States or Government decided to formalize the Southern African<br />

development Coordinating Conference (<strong>SADC</strong>C) which had as first name Southern Africa: Towards<br />

<strong>Economic</strong> Liberation. This declaration had at that time the aim at economic liberation <strong>and</strong><br />

integrated <strong>and</strong> equitable development <strong>of</strong> the economies <strong>of</strong> the region. <strong>The</strong> <strong>SADC</strong>C turned out with<br />

a legal existence in August 1992, <strong>and</strong> is forth named as the Southern African Development<br />

Community (<strong>SADC</strong>). In the 2000 Ordinary Summit, a protocol to establish the tribunal was signed<br />

in Namibia. <strong>The</strong> tribunal was to onwards ensure the proper usage <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the <strong>SADC</strong><br />

treaty <strong>and</strong> remedial actions upon disputes that may occur. <strong>The</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> treaty was amended in August<br />

2001 by the Head <strong>of</strong> State <strong>and</strong> Government <strong>and</strong> the protocol was subject to amendments in<br />

October 2002.<br />

In 2008, <strong>SADC</strong> joined the Common Market For Eastern <strong>and</strong> Southern Africa <strong>and</strong> the East African<br />

Community to form the African Free Trade Zone. As such, <strong>SADC</strong> subscribed to create a single free<br />

trade zone composing <strong>of</strong> 26 countries. Moreover, the <strong>SADC</strong> trade protocol <strong>of</strong> 2000 which


pronounced the reduction <strong>of</strong> custom duties is to be carried forward to further reduction to around<br />

85% <strong>of</strong> tariff lines by 2008 <strong>and</strong> on tariffs on sensitive products being eliminated by this year.<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> has had 15 member states but after the coup d’état Madagascar was suspended, hence <strong>SADC</strong><br />

has 14 active member states presently; Angola, Botswana, Democratic Republic <strong>of</strong> Congo, Lesotho,<br />

Malawi, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Seychelles, South Africa, Swazil<strong>and</strong>, Tanzania, Zambia,<br />

Zimbabwe.<br />

AFRICAN RECS AVERAGE EXPORTS TO THE REST OF AFRICA IN US$<br />

MILLIONS, 2000-2008<br />

At the global level, Africa’s share in global exports increased from 2.4 per cent in 2000 to 2.9 per<br />

cent in 2008, but averaged about 2.5 per cent between these periods. On the import side, Africa<br />

constituted only 2 per cent <strong>of</strong> total world imports over the same period. <strong>The</strong>se statistics confirm<br />

Africa’s infinitesimal share in global trade (UNECA, 2010).<br />

Africa is increasingly focusing on regional integration as a strategy for achieving sustainable<br />

economic growth as there is a consensus that by merging its economies <strong>and</strong> pooling its capacities,<br />

endowments <strong>and</strong> energies, the continent can overcome its daunting development challenges.<br />

However, there are still a number <strong>of</strong> constraints <strong>and</strong> challenges facing regional trading blocs in<br />

Africa.<br />

Intra-REC trade in particular <strong>and</strong> intra-African trade in general, is generally low. African countries<br />

in general tend to trade more with countries outside the continent than among themselves. <strong>The</strong><br />

most important trading partners are the EU <strong>and</strong> USA, although China in particular <strong>and</strong> Asia in<br />

general are increasingly also becoming important destinations for Africa’s exports <strong>and</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> its<br />

imports.<br />

As figure xx illustrates, on average, countries within CEN-SAD (<strong>The</strong> Community <strong>of</strong> Sahel-Saharan<br />

States) registered the highest exports beyond their borders to the rest <strong>of</strong> African countries, followed<br />

by <strong>SADC</strong>, ECOWAS (<strong>Economic</strong> Community <strong>of</strong> West African States), UEMOA (West African<br />

<strong>Economic</strong> <strong>and</strong> Monetary Union) <strong>and</strong> COMESA.<br />

Figure xx RECs Average Export Share to the Rest <strong>of</strong> Africa, US$ million, 2000-2008


Further, we note that the RECS’ major export destinations are the EU <strong>and</strong> USA, which constitute an<br />

average <strong>of</strong> 57 per cent <strong>of</strong> the exports <strong>of</strong> the African RECs. For some RECs, the EU <strong>and</strong> USA<br />

comprise more than 60 per cent <strong>of</strong> their export markets (see table). For RECs such as IOC <strong>and</strong><br />

UMA, about 80 per cent <strong>of</strong> their exports were destined, between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2008, for the EU <strong>and</strong><br />

USA markets. Asia, <strong>and</strong> China in particular are important export markets for the RECs.<br />

Table: Direction <strong>of</strong> African RECs’ exports to African <strong>and</strong> non-African countries in US$<br />

millions, average between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2008


Source: UNECA, 2010<br />

AFRICAN RECS AVERAGE IMPORTS TO AFRICAN AND NON-AFRICAN<br />

COUNTRIES IN US$ MILLIONS, 2000-2008<br />

<strong>The</strong> major sources <strong>of</strong> imports to Africa lie outside the continent. However, it is interesting to<br />

observe that within CEPGL (<strong>Economic</strong> Community <strong>of</strong> the Great Lakes Countries); Africa was a<br />

significant source <strong>of</strong> imports to the community, representing about 42 per cent <strong>of</strong> the total imports.<br />

About a fourth <strong>of</strong> imports by UEMOA also came from Africa. But for the rest <strong>of</strong> the RECs, the EU<br />

continues to be a major source <strong>of</strong> imports. This is shown in table 4.2 below.<br />

Table : African RECs average imports to African <strong>and</strong> non-African countries in US$ millions,<br />

2000-2008


OVERALL TRADE PERFORMANCE OF THE <strong>SADC</strong><br />

Source: UNECA, 2010<br />

Since 2006, global exports to <strong>SADC</strong> increase at a higher rate than imports from the region. Overall,<br />

global imports from the <strong>SADC</strong> region increase by 140 per cent between 2004 <strong>and</strong> 2008. <strong>The</strong> main<br />

products imported by the <strong>SADC</strong> region globally include mineral fuels, nuclear machinery, iron ore<br />

materials <strong>and</strong> vehicles. <strong>The</strong> highest growth imports between 2004 <strong>and</strong> 2008 are fertilizers, nickel<br />

articles <strong>and</strong> iron ore articles, with imports <strong>of</strong> fertilizers growing 347 per cent, imports <strong>of</strong> nickel<br />

articles growing 301.4 per cent <strong>and</strong> imports <strong>of</strong> iron ore articles growing 372 per cent. Overall, global<br />

exports from the <strong>SADC</strong> region increase by 194.4 per cent from 2004 to 2008. <strong>The</strong> global export<br />

basket <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> closely mirrors the import basket, with high growth <strong>of</strong> exports <strong>of</strong> mineral fuels (456<br />

per cent), iron ore products (527 per cent) <strong>and</strong> copper <strong>and</strong> copper articles (361.7 per cent)<br />

(Trademap, 2010).<br />

<strong>The</strong> main products traded between the <strong>SADC</strong> countries are mineral fuels, nuclear machinery <strong>and</strong><br />

iron ore products. <strong>The</strong> growth in the trade <strong>of</strong> print media such as newspapers, books <strong>and</strong> pictures<br />

has seen an increase <strong>of</strong> 395 per cent from 2004 to 2008. Other high-growth products include<br />

cereals, iron ore products, nickel products <strong>and</strong> mineral fuels.


Figure : Overall Trade Performance <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong>, 2004-2008<br />

SOURCES OF THE <strong>SADC</strong> AVERAGE IMPORTS IN US$ MILLIONS, 2000-2008<br />

Table : Main Import Sources <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong>, 2000-2008.<br />

<strong>SADC</strong><br />

<strong>SADC</strong><br />

(%)<br />

Africa 8584.76 11.8<br />

China 5949.47 8.2<br />

Asia 8133.55 11.2<br />

EU 25872.92 35.6<br />

Japan 3922.57 5.4<br />

USA 5713.28 7.9<br />

Rest <strong>of</strong> World 14590.9 20.1<br />

Total WORLD 72767.4 100<br />

Source: UN COMTRADE Database


Figure : Main Import Sources <strong>of</strong> EAC, COMESA <strong>and</strong> <strong>SADC</strong>, 2000-2008.<br />

DESTINATION OF THE <strong>SADC</strong> AVERAGE EXPORTS IN US$ MILLIONS, 2000-2008<br />

Table: An Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Main Export Destinations <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong>, 2000-2008<br />

Main Export<br />

Destinations between<br />

2000-2008 <strong>SADC</strong><br />

<strong>SADC</strong><br />

(%)<br />

Africa 8,704.9 12.3<br />

China 7,139.5 10.1<br />

Asia 5,184.6 7.3<br />

EU 20,679.4 29.3<br />

Japan 2,672.8 3.8<br />

USA 11,266.5 16.0<br />

Rest <strong>of</strong> World 14,973.9 21.2<br />

WORLD 70,621.6 100


Source: UN COMTRADE Database<br />

Figure xx: Main Export Destinations <strong>of</strong> EAC, COMESA <strong>and</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> between 2000-2008<br />

<strong>The</strong> table below gives an interesting comparative percentage share <strong>of</strong> trade <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> <strong>and</strong> non<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> <strong>and</strong> shows the relatively low level trade within <strong>SADC</strong> member countries.<br />

Year<br />

Imports Exports<br />

Total (Rs m) <strong>SADC</strong> (Rs000) % <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> Total (Rs m) <strong>SADC</strong> (Rs000) % <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong><br />

2005 93,282 9,619,469 10.31 59,095 4,385,816 7.42<br />

2006 115,502 9,899,775 8.57 68,966 5,064,698 7.34<br />

2007 121,037 11,692,049 9.66 64,265 6,708,746 10.44<br />

2008 132,165 13,232,380 10.01 59,015 6,615,338 11.21<br />

2009 118,444 11,973,066 10.11 56,162 7,370,816 13.12<br />

2010 134,882 13,517,218 10.02 61,990 8,217,470 13.26<br />

INTRA TRADE:<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> patterns <strong>of</strong> Trade<br />

As shown in the table below, the shares <strong>of</strong> exports <strong>and</strong> imports to the <strong>SADC</strong> members over the<br />

period 2000 to 2011 vary greatly. <strong>The</strong> table was constructed by considering the total imports <strong>and</strong>


exports <strong>of</strong> each country over the period 2000 to 2011 <strong>and</strong> compared to the overall imports <strong>and</strong><br />

exports <strong>of</strong> all fourteen countries over that same period.<br />

Row Labels Exports (%) Imports (%)<br />

Angola 0.61 0.04<br />

Botswana 0.20 0.10<br />

Congo, Dem. Rep. 0.06 0.10<br />

Lesotho 0.26 0.21<br />

Madagascar 54.57 6.41<br />

Malawi 0.29 0.27<br />

Mozambique 0.90 2.06<br />

Namibia 0.06 0.20<br />

Seychelles 8.32 3.86<br />

South Africa 31.20 80.58<br />

Swazil<strong>and</strong> 0.05 2.16<br />

Tanzania 1.26 0.56<br />

Zambia 0.46 2.32<br />

Zimbabwe 1.77 1.15<br />

Table 4.<br />

Madagascar <strong>and</strong> South Africa dominate trade with 54.6% <strong>and</strong> 31.20% <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> exports over the<br />

period respectively. However as mentioned earlier, Mauritius’ overall world exports fails to countries<br />

in <strong>SADC</strong> as exports are concentrated elsewhere than in <strong>SADC</strong>. <strong>The</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> falls well behind that <strong>of</strong><br />

EU for example. <strong>The</strong> products are supported by several initiatives, namely Everything But Arms<br />

(EBA) initiative, the Lome Convention amongst others. Some countries may have preferential<br />

market access in the EU. In addition to that, Mauritius flow <strong>of</strong> exports is more <strong>of</strong>ten dealt with in<br />

COMESA than in <strong>SADC</strong>. Nonetheless back to the consideration <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> only, it is to be<br />

mentioned that Madagascar was expelled during that period, <strong>and</strong> yet stayed the first ranked <strong>of</strong><br />

importing from Mauritius. <strong>The</strong> second best in exports is South Africa, clearly seen from the table.<br />

In Imports, both countries are still the two best ranked. South Africa with a highly differential<br />

percentage compared to the others (80.58%) <strong>and</strong> Madagascar laying far behind but yet the second<br />

best ranked at 6.41% <strong>of</strong> imports to Mauritius. Again, the analysis <strong>of</strong> patterns <strong>of</strong> trade for Mauritius


should not be restricted to import volumes in <strong>SADC</strong> only but should also consider other <strong>RTA</strong>s as<br />

imports may be more significant in other <strong>RTA</strong>s.<br />

Hence it should be noted that both Madagascar <strong>and</strong> South Africa was relatively more important in<br />

exports <strong>and</strong> imports to the region in that period as compared to the other member states whose<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> total trade in the region for Mauritius are very low.<br />

INTRA-REC EXPORT TRENDS IN US$ MILLIONS, 2000-2008<br />

In general, intra-REC exports have been growing in value across most RECs. On average between<br />

2000 <strong>and</strong> 2007, the top five RECs in intra-REC exports in value terms are CEN-SAD (25 per cent),<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> (25 per cent), ECOWAS (17 per cent), COMESA (12 per cent) <strong>and</strong> UMA (7 per cent). <strong>The</strong><br />

RECs that traded least among themselves, at 1 per cent or less, on average between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2007<br />

are CEMAC, ECCAS, CEPGL <strong>and</strong> MRU (UNECA, 2010).<br />

Figure : Intra-REC exports 2000-2008 (in US$ millions)<br />

As far as COMESA, <strong>SADC</strong> <strong>and</strong> EAC are concerned, their trend <strong>of</strong> intra-REC exports from 2000-<br />

2008 is shown in Figure below. Our data confirms that <strong>SADC</strong> intra-exports potential is much<br />

higher than that <strong>of</strong> COMESA <strong>and</strong> the EAC.<br />

Figure xx EAC, COMESA <strong>and</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> intra-exports between 2000-2008


Table: Share <strong>of</strong> Individual Country’s Exports in total Intra-Exports within <strong>SADC</strong>, 2000-2008<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

Angola 0.2 0.04 0.9 0.1 10.6 11.6 8.9 32.1 8.7<br />

DRC 0.2 2.3 0.6 1.0 1.1 1.3 1.6 3.1 3.8<br />

Madagascar 0.5 0.7 1.2 3.2 1.3 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.5<br />

Malawi 1.2 1.3 4.3 4.5 4.5 5.0 4.1 3.6 4.1<br />

Mauritius 2.2 3.0 7.6 8.1 5.7 5.8 3.9 3.8 4.3<br />

Mozambique 3.0 4.1 12.8 12.3 11.6 15.2 11.5 10.2 12.2<br />

South Africa 73.7 76.4 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a<br />

Tanzania 1.2 0.9 5.5 4.9 5.2 6.9 4.7 3.8 4.3<br />

Zambia 6.8 7.2 22.8 21.8 30.7 26.7 53.4 19.6 31.0<br />

Zimbabwe 10.8 4.0 44.4 44.0 29.2 26.9 11.5 23.3 31.0<br />

Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: UN COMTRADE Database<br />

INTRA-REC IMPORT TRENDS IN US$ MILLIONS, 2000-2008<br />

Figure provides data on the value <strong>of</strong> intra-REC imports in $US millions. As in the <strong>case</strong> <strong>of</strong> exports,<br />

intra-REC imports also have witnessed a growing trend in value across most RECs. On average,<br />

between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2007, the top five RECs in intra-REC imports were CEN-SAD (26 per cent),<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> (25 per cent), ECOWAS (17 per cent), COMESA (12 per cent) <strong>and</strong> UMA (7 per cent). <strong>The</strong><br />

same RECs also dominate intra-REC exports. On average, between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2007, the most<br />

significant importing countries among these top five RECs in terms <strong>of</strong> intra-community imports<br />

were:


•CEN-SAD: Egypt (24 per cent), Nigeria (16 per cent), Morocco (15 per cent) <strong>and</strong> Tunisia (11 per<br />

cent);<br />

•<strong>SADC</strong>: South Africa (69 per cent) <strong>and</strong> Angola (9 per cent); <strong>and</strong><br />

•ECOWAS: Nigeria (40 per cent), Liberia (14 per cent), Ghana (11 per cent) <strong>and</strong> Cote d’Ivoire (9<br />

per cent)<br />

Figure: Intra-REC imports, 2000-2008, in US$ millions<br />

With regards to COMESA, <strong>SADC</strong> <strong>and</strong> EAC, their trend <strong>of</strong> intra-REC imports from 2000-2008 is<br />

shown in Figure below. Our data confirms that <strong>SADC</strong> intra-imports potential is much higher than<br />

that <strong>of</strong> COMESA <strong>and</strong> the EAC.<br />

Figure: EAC, COMESA <strong>and</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> intra-imports between 2000-2008, US$ million


<strong>SADC</strong> <strong>and</strong> Mauritius<br />

Mauritius, being one amongst the developing countries, has been an active member <strong>of</strong> WTO since 1<br />

January 1995 3 . Mauritius as a developing economy benefits from the MFN rules. Mauritius is<br />

actually a member <strong>of</strong> three <strong>RTA</strong>s in force. Moreover Mauritius find itself engaged in other<br />

agreements; such as the Indian Ocean Commission (COI), Cross Border Initiative (CBI) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Indian Ocean Rim Association (IOR-ARC); (Figure 3).<br />

Figure .<br />

As an affiliate to <strong>RTA</strong>s, Mauritius expects a welfare gain. This has lead Mauritius to sign different<br />

agreements which differs in the conditions <strong>of</strong> trade. This is pointed out in the “spaghetti bowl”<br />

phenomenon by Bhagwati (1993). Recently, Mauritius has negotiated an agreement; Eastern<br />

Southern Africa (EPA), with the EU which came into force in May 2012. <strong>The</strong> EU is an important<br />

trading partner for Mauritius <strong>and</strong> Mauritius greatly benefits from the EU Protocols on sugar.<br />

According to statistics, the EU is the main export market for Mauritius as it comprises <strong>of</strong> 63.7% <strong>of</strong><br />

total exports in 2010.<br />

By main destination (2010) Exports (%)<br />

3 Source from WTO site.


European Union 63.7<br />

United states 10.9<br />

Madagascar 5.5<br />

South Africa 4.5<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> 1.8<br />

Table 1.<br />

By main origin (2010) Imports (%)<br />

European Union 22.9<br />

India 22.3<br />

China 13.3<br />

South Africa 8.4<br />

Japan 3.3<br />

Table 2.<br />

<strong>The</strong> main export commodities for Mauritius are textiles, garment products <strong>and</strong> sugar. Mauritius not<br />

only benefit from the MFN tariffs but also gain highly from the Cotonou Sugar Protocol that<br />

guarantees the purchase <strong>of</strong> 507,000 tons <strong>of</strong> sugar per annum at an established price. Mauritius has<br />

diversified its trade with the EU significantly; it exp<strong>and</strong>ed its exports basket to textiles, garments,<br />

<strong>and</strong> even aircraft parts. Mauritius is very dependent on the EU market <strong>and</strong> on EU preferences for<br />

sugar. Even though a non-reciprocal trade relation persists between Mauritius <strong>and</strong> EU, Mauritius,<br />

classified as a middle-income country, still gain from their transactions. In recent past, Mauritius<br />

thought upon negotiating a “Southern-Eastern Africa EPA” that contains mainly COMESA states<br />

but excludes SACU countries. Mauritius undertook that action to improve trade or market relations<br />

with COMESA members. By that action, Mauritius showed an aversion to adopt the EU South<br />

Africa liberalisation schedule. Mauritius economic healthiness is threatened by increasing worldwide<br />

competition <strong>and</strong> limited protection options in trade. <strong>The</strong> EU brought the requirement for “double<br />

transformation” to help African, Carribean <strong>and</strong> Pacific countries (ACP) on market. However, this<br />

was not really helpful to Mauritius.<br />

Moreover, the reform <strong>of</strong> the European Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), which is to lower<br />

subsidies on specific crop production, if implemented, will result in a negative effect on Mauritius; as<br />

the value <strong>of</strong> the Protocol commodies will be reduced. In addition to that, the European “Everything


ut Arms” (EBA) scheme gave all least developed countries (LDCs) a duty free market access on<br />

sugar since 2009 <strong>and</strong> this leads to an increase in competition in the EU market. Mauritius again<br />

suffered a negative impact on its market share. Hence in Mauritius history, EU helped the growth <strong>of</strong><br />

Mauritius.<br />

Mauritius is an example <strong>of</strong> countries that have interests in <strong>SADC</strong>. <strong>The</strong> trade transactions <strong>of</strong><br />

Mauritius are frequentius in COMESA countries compared to <strong>SADC</strong> countries. Mauritius receives<br />

8.4% <strong>of</strong> its total imports from South Africa. However, South Africa is not perceived as an attractive<br />

destination for Mauritius exports. <strong>The</strong> reasons are Mauritius faces substantial barriers on trade <strong>and</strong><br />

its main export commodities are regarded as sensitive in the SACU. Although, it cannot be ignored<br />

that Africa is one <strong>of</strong> the major investor in Mauritius.<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> lacks importance in Mauritius compared to COMESA as the trade <strong>of</strong> its main products is not<br />

that much solid in <strong>SADC</strong>. <strong>The</strong> range <strong>of</strong> products traded in COMESA has changed much through<br />

the period 1980 to 2002. Mauritius has increased its trade considerably since that period by around<br />

30%. Pondering over COMESA, Mauritius has been a member <strong>of</strong> the Preferential Trade Area<br />

before COMESA. Mauritius gained from the Free Trade Area in 2000, which exclude all customs<br />

duties on imports from COMESA members. Mauritius was already heading from sugar industry to<br />

textile industry <strong>and</strong> yet the fact that Mauritius benefits from trade in COMESA still persists. This<br />

statement is proven considering the main trading partner for Mauritius lies in COMESA.<br />

Madagascar imports around 75% <strong>of</strong> Mauritius total exports <strong>and</strong> Egypt, is 29% approximately <strong>of</strong><br />

Mauritius total imports. Moreover any decisions taken in COMESA custom union benefits<br />

Mauritius. <strong>The</strong> export markets <strong>of</strong> Mauritius are still undiversified in COMESA compared to the EU.<br />

<strong>The</strong> export rate is made up <strong>of</strong> only 6.8% in COMESA. As mentioned earlier, trade volume increased<br />

since the time Mauritius entered into the agreement. Moreover, Mauritius was one among the five<br />

chosen countries to promote the project <strong>of</strong> Trading Houses. Mauritius will enhance its<br />

competitiveness on the services market; beneficial.<br />

Concerning the Indian Ocean Commission (COI), Mauritius was member since foundation. This<br />

small organization is also known as the Commission de l'Océan Indien in French caters for the<br />

cooperation between Comoros, Madagascar, Mauritius, Reunion <strong>and</strong> Seychelles. <strong>The</strong> main idea <strong>of</strong><br />

the foundation was to promote trade <strong>and</strong> tourism. Not much research was carried on this agreement


ut it can be said that it does not have enormous impact on the GDP <strong>of</strong> Mauritius. However,<br />

Mauritius finds itself in a better place with its projects <strong>and</strong> laws.<br />

Cross Border Initiatives (CBI) was agreed by the Minister <strong>of</strong> Foreign Affairs. Recently, food security<br />

was highlighted in Mauritius <strong>and</strong> a project came up. This was idealized on agricultural cultivation<br />

outside <strong>of</strong> Mauritius for its citizens with a budget <strong>of</strong> Rs1 billion in 2009.<br />

This negotiation has not only smoothened the relationship with foreigners but also encourage trade<br />

flows. Moreover, Mauritius has the opportunity to rent the l<strong>and</strong> acquired to other investors. Cross<br />

Border Initiatives facilitates the movements <strong>of</strong> people among the countries. Mauritius was no<br />

exception not to follow the trend to invest in outside economy for agricultural cultivation. Not to<br />

mention that the agreement also takes into consideration social factors like; child exploitation <strong>and</strong><br />

human trafficking. Hence this agreement benefits go two ways; the host <strong>and</strong> the foreign country.<br />

With this kind <strong>of</strong> integration, Mauritius does secure its social stability which enforces the economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> political stability; thus its growth has achieved reached a long term base.<br />

Mauritius is engaged in the Indian Ocean Rim-Association for Regional Cooperation (IOR-ARC),<br />

also known as the Indian Ocean Rim Initiative, for quite a long time. This initiative allows<br />

information flows to positively influence trade <strong>and</strong> investment. This agreement also favors mutual<br />

interests, growth <strong>and</strong> development. Trade flows had increased in goods, services <strong>and</strong> even scientific<br />

<strong>and</strong> technological sharing, as Mauritius gains from reduction <strong>and</strong> eradication <strong>of</strong> some barriers.<br />

Mauritius participates in the projects undertaken by the organization. Mauritius enjoys good<br />

cooperation <strong>and</strong> liaison settled by the initiative. Not to forget that Mauritius highly benefits in terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> trade <strong>and</strong> growth from being member in this region.<br />

Mauritius was welcomed as the twelfth member at the Annual Conference <strong>of</strong> the (Inter-state<br />

Defence <strong>and</strong> Security Committee) ISDSC that was held in Lilongwe during October 1996. Mauritius<br />

gained a lot <strong>of</strong> international experience as from its dependence <strong>and</strong> is now an export oriented unit.<br />

Being a member <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> for the few years, it is now an exemplary country that provides an<br />

excellent <strong>case</strong> study <strong>of</strong> the economic achievements that are possible through outward-oriented trade<br />

policies. <strong>The</strong> topic <strong>of</strong> interest for Mauritius in <strong>SADC</strong> is acutely based on textiles <strong>and</strong> garments.<br />

Mauritius is one <strong>of</strong> the few manufacturing sectors in which there is significant production in a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> member countries. Mauritius was since long time known for its h<strong>and</strong> make production;


workforce. <strong>The</strong> difference in the workforce degree <strong>and</strong> other determinants <strong>of</strong> comparative costs,<br />

amongst member states, at the different stages in the industry means that there exist some sections<br />

that can be exploited altogether (through trade initiatives). Consequently, this may enhance the<br />

region’s global competitiveness. This is where Mauritius showed its capacity <strong>and</strong> laid the region’s<br />

potential.<br />

Opportunities for Mauritius to set strategic alliances through the Africa <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>and</strong> Opportunities<br />

Act (AGOA) have recently exploded. Mauritius needs, at the earliest, to remedy its domestic <strong>and</strong><br />

regional weaknesses to better exploit the American market while taking advantage <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong><br />

underutilized textile plants. Mauritius being one <strong>of</strong> the dominant players in the textile <strong>and</strong> garment<br />

sector <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> has led to different objectives towards interests <strong>and</strong> approaches to <strong>SADC</strong>.


<strong>SADC</strong> Members 1970 1975 1978 1988 1990 1992 1995 2000 2005 2010<br />

Import 2.819 0.923 3 4 6 8 9 10 10 1977.472<br />

Angola<br />

Export 0 0 2 3 6 7 7 35.656 1916.575<br />

Total 2.819 0.923 5 7 12 15 16 10 45.656 3894.047<br />

Botswana<br />

Congo<br />

Lesotho<br />

Madagascar<br />

Malawi<br />

Mozambique<br />

Namibia<br />

Seychelles<br />

South Africa<br />

Swazil<strong>and</strong><br />

Tanzania<br />

Zambia<br />

Zimbabwe<br />

Gr<strong>and</strong> Total<br />

Import 3 5 6 6 6 7 7 12.581 381.428 27.481<br />

Export 60 80 80 80 90 90 90 681.098 150.038 106.902<br />

Total 63 85 86 86 96 97 97 693.679 531.466 134.383<br />

Import 6.33 4.00 7.00 558.57 491.57 185.57 185.90 6.64 19.00<br />

Export 30 34.00 38.69 66.62 459.78 45.27 24.00 4.00 8.00<br />

Total 30 40.33 42.69 7.00 625.19 951.35 230.83 209.90 10.64 27.00<br />

Import 0 56 34 34 434 34 5 5 779.286 2037.939<br />

Export 3 3 3 5 5 5 6 6 0 0<br />

Total 3 59 37 39 439 39 11 11 779.286 2037.939<br />

Import 1512.237 2662.187 1209.952 3579.072 11723.3 15583.97 20340.15 33485.41 14758.28 18466.53<br />

Export 216.205 165.686 219.152 2076.004 9660.502 15138.2 39798.93 76077.54 40777.59 47012.01<br />

Total 1728.442 2827.873 1429.104 5655.076 21383.8 30722.18 60139.08 109562.9 55535.87 65478.54<br />

Import 0.809 7.175 59.749 671.076 421.924 310.379 129.232 1091.474 84.737 1479.613<br />

Export 11.16 1.48 13.353 38 136.148 133.838 525.627 1256.885 125.256 184.433<br />

Total 11.969 8.655 73.102 709.076 558.072 444.217 654.859 2348.359 209.993 1664.046<br />

Import 31.227 529.329 343 234 47.398 144.258 119.539 1932.181 15590.03 3987.792<br />

Export 6.194 0 5.533 0 1.144 1110.463 193.714 958.086 783.393 1286.569<br />

Total 37.421 529.329 348.533 234 48.542 1254.721 313.253 2890.267 16373.42 5274.361<br />

Import 50 100 130 140 160 180 210 270.907 308.017 949.311<br />

Export 0 1 8 8 9 8 11 8.681 42.089 134.01<br />

Total 50 101 138 148 169 188 221 279.588 350.106 1083.321<br />

Import 215.082 350.344 530.702 454 95.874 1190.437 228.761 962.17 9531.7 13909.6<br />

Export 37.806 1192.475 607.637 963.859 3210.592 2653.202 2601.462 5487.792 5572.723 8823.775<br />

Total 252.888 1542.819 1138.339 1417.859 3306.466 3843.639 2830.223 6449.962 15104.42 22733.38<br />

Import 6808.213 32085.17 58560.43 110503.8 148802.9 232188.8 225567.6 309354.1 270782.2 370538<br />

Export 1873.451 3136.947 6168.379 4745.152 6755.176 12276.22 6798.884 8956.243 18337.5 72211.29<br />

Total 8681.664 35222.12 64728.81 115249 155558.1 244465.1 232366.5 318310.3 289119.7 442749.3<br />

Import 1200 2455 3345 3676 3600 3967 4700 5934.701 6602.039 8486.699<br />

Export 9 22 26 26 26 26 30 709.232 4.765 0.359<br />

Total 1209 2477 3371 3702 3626 3993 4730 6643.933 6606.804 8487.058<br />

Import 204.674 23.254 150.283 176 425.673 1643.242 1611.453 980.388 2615.564 3501.441<br />

Export 0 0 46.58 60 81.236 629.348 936.839 2466.208 1575.435 491.221<br />

Total 204.674 23.254 196.863 236 506.909 2272.59 2548.292 3446.596 4190.999 3992.662<br />

Import 12.675 6.277 0.865 1 15.106 0.789 12.036 188.644 8608.924 6273.059<br />

Export 21.453 308.604 348.941 354 293.412 1076.758 251.385 139.872 380.853 125<br />

Total 34.128 314.881 349.806 355 308.518 1077.547 263.421 328.516 8989.777 6398.059<br />

Import 1 7 8 55 2685.837 4120.532 9030.824 6790.873 2848.988 6737.36<br />

Export 2000 2500 2904 3000 3205.709 3617.519 6608.415 5784.288 786.803 1077.147<br />

Total 2001 2507 2912 3055 5891.546 7738.051 15639.24 12575.16 3635.791 7814.507<br />

Import 75580.74 330672.8 498367.9 1286005 1686320 1773675 1985819 2078052 3152118 4379043<br />

Export 67531.41 294594.8 320222.9 997519.9 1220503 1335501 1537690 1489616 1560305 1489806<br />

Total 143112.2 625267.6 818590.8 2283525 2906823 3109176 3523509 3567668 4712423 5868850


Mauritian exports to the <strong>SADC</strong> member states had experienced a steady moving from 2000 to 2011.<br />

This upward <strong>and</strong> downward trend is expected to continue with new policies <strong>of</strong> reducing or phasing<br />

out tariff by <strong>SADC</strong> countries. Some <strong>of</strong> the commodities that are dealt with for Mauritius are Fabrics,<br />

T-shirts, Jerseys, Soaps, Wheat pellets, Baby Napkins, Sunglasses, Cotton Fabrics, Food<br />

preparations Chemicals, Printed books, <strong>and</strong> Articles <strong>of</strong> plastic.<br />

<strong>The</strong> increase in exports to South Africa was mainly linked to non-industrial diamond, which covered<br />

<strong>of</strong> about 40% <strong>of</strong> total export earnings in 2003. <strong>The</strong> main products, 33% <strong>of</strong> total exports to South<br />

Africa, were textiles <strong>and</strong> garments. Other products such as baby napkins, soaps, printed books <strong>and</strong><br />

sunglasses were also highly considered in exports considerations. Under the <strong>SADC</strong> protocol, tariffs<br />

on cotton fabrics have declined from 30% to 25% when exported to Mozambique in the region <strong>and</strong><br />

duties on fertilizers have reduced to nil in 2000. Exports to Tanzania rose significantly just after the<br />

20 th century. Namibia has also experienced an increase in exports due to the exportation <strong>of</strong><br />

machinery (98% <strong>of</strong> total exports in 2003). For other countries such as Botswana <strong>and</strong> Lesotho,<br />

exports to these have decrease over the years up till now. <strong>The</strong> reason is that the main exporting<br />

products have lost market share, despite the fact that new products, for instance paper <strong>and</strong><br />

paperboard labels, were exported. <strong>The</strong> agreement on tariff phasing-down plan was made in the year<br />

2000 in respect to imports from all <strong>SADC</strong> member states, except for imports from South Africa<br />

which started in early <strong>of</strong> 2003. Plan adapted to sensitive products began in 2008. It is to be noted<br />

that South Africa remained the major trading partner in <strong>SADC</strong> region, <strong>and</strong> for Mauritius. Imports<br />

from member countries, to be precise Mozambique, Namibia, Botswana amongst others, has gained<br />

momentum in the period considered above (2000 to 2011). Digging down to history, the increase in<br />

imports from Botswana was linked mainly to the bovine meat, Mozambique increase <strong>of</strong> exports to<br />

Mauritius was due to the fact that tariff on coal has reduced significantly over the years, Namibia<br />

because <strong>of</strong> the increase in the imports <strong>of</strong> frozen fish amongst others. <strong>The</strong>re is a fundamental point<br />

to be exposed; the increase in imports in 2004 is mainly attributed to the imports <strong>of</strong> jet fuels <strong>and</strong><br />

motor spirit which is not related to the tariff phased down approach.<br />

METHODOLOGY<br />

In this section, we try to evaluate the link between <strong>SADC</strong> exports <strong>and</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> economic growth,<br />

through a regression analysis. To model the growth effects <strong>of</strong> trade in the <strong>SADC</strong> region, a classical<br />

economic growth function was extended with st<strong>and</strong>ard control variables such as investment,


education, labour, financial development <strong>and</strong> trade openness. This is consistent with works from the<br />

literature (Barro, 1991; Mankiw, Romer <strong>and</strong> Weil, 1992; Benhabib <strong>and</strong> Spiegel, 1994; Levine <strong>and</strong><br />

Renelt; 1992, Levine et al, 2000 among others & Seetanah <strong>and</strong> Khadaroo, 2008). More importantly<br />

for the sake <strong>of</strong> this study the <strong>SADC</strong> exports has been decoupled into exports <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> countries to<br />

their member states <strong>and</strong> into exports to other non-<strong>SADC</strong> countries. This will permit us to gauge the<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> trade on economic development. <strong>The</strong> implied theoretical model is thus<br />

Y = f ( IVT,<br />

EDU,<br />

LAB,<br />

FD,<br />

<strong>SADC</strong>,<br />

NON<strong>SADC</strong>)<br />

(1)<br />

Y denotes the respective <strong>SADC</strong>members economy’s output (measured as the real Gross Domestic<br />

Products at constant price in US$), IVT is the level <strong>of</strong> investment in the country (measured as the<br />

investment ratio), EDU is the level <strong>of</strong> literacy <strong>and</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> labour (measured by the secondary<br />

enrolment ratio), LAB is the labour force (measured as the number <strong>of</strong> people in employment), FD is<br />

the level <strong>of</strong> financial development (measured by the ratio <strong>of</strong> liquid Assets to GDP), <strong>SADC</strong> is the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> export to <strong>SADC</strong> member states <strong>and</strong> NON<strong>SADC</strong> is the amount <strong>of</strong> export to NON<strong>SADC</strong><br />

countries (both measured as a percentage <strong>of</strong> GDP). <strong>The</strong> data series for OUTPUT, IVT, FD were<br />

generated from the International Financial Statistic (IFS) various yearbooks, the secondary<br />

enrolment ratio from the World Development Report (various issues) <strong>and</strong> the two sets <strong>of</strong> data on<br />

exports have been constructed from World Trade Analyzer.<br />

ANALYSIS<br />

<strong>The</strong> Econometric Model <strong>and</strong> preliminary tests<br />

Recall equation 1 above <strong>and</strong> taking logs on both sides <strong>of</strong> the equation <strong>and</strong> denoting the lower<strong>case</strong><br />

variables as the natural log <strong>of</strong> the respective upper<strong>case</strong> variable results in the following:<br />

y ε<br />

it = β 0 + β1ivtit<br />

+ β 2eduit<br />

+ β3lit<br />

+ β 4 fdit<br />

+ β5sadcit<br />

+ β6nonsadcit<br />

+ it (2)<br />

where β0 is the constant term, β1 , β2 , β3, β4, β5 <strong>and</strong> β6 represent the elasticity <strong>of</strong> output relative to<br />

investment , education, labour, financial development, trade to <strong>SADC</strong> states <strong>and</strong> trade to<br />

NON<strong>SADC</strong> states. i denotes the respective countries in the sample <strong>and</strong> t the time period, that is<br />

1995-2008.


Analysis <strong>and</strong> Results<br />

Given the limitations <strong>of</strong> using a single-equation OLS cross sectional regression model <strong>and</strong> pooled<br />

OLS (see Kennedy, 2003) panel data techniques are used. In this section we employ both static <strong>and</strong><br />

dynamic (Generalised Methods <strong>of</strong> Moments) techniques to gauge the relationship between <strong>SADC</strong><br />

trade <strong>and</strong> economic performance. In fact, use <strong>of</strong> panel data allows not only to control for<br />

unobserved cross country heterogeneity but also to investigate dynamic relations.<br />

We use the Hausman test to test the use <strong>of</strong> a r<strong>and</strong>om or fixed effect estimator. <strong>The</strong> Hausman test<br />

tests the null hypothesis that the coefficients estimated by the efficient r<strong>and</strong>om effects estimator are<br />

the same as the ones estimated by the consistent fixed effects estimator. <strong>The</strong> specification test<br />

recommended the use <strong>of</strong> r<strong>and</strong>om effects model. <strong>The</strong> null hypothesis <strong>of</strong> homoskedasticity was<br />

rejected at 1% <strong>and</strong> the last column presents the P(h), the heteroskedastic consistent estimates the<br />

effects coefficients <strong>of</strong> the extended growth equation specified previously.<br />

It is shown that <strong>SADC</strong> trade, has had a positive contribution to economic growth <strong>of</strong> Member states,<br />

although to a much lesser extent as compared to non <strong>SADC</strong> trade. In fact the coefficient <strong>of</strong> 0.16, a<br />

measure <strong>of</strong> output elasticity, means that a one percent increase in <strong>SADC</strong> trade contributes to 0.16<br />

percent increase in the GDP <strong>of</strong> member states. It is noteworthy that non <strong>SADC</strong> trade is much more<br />

important than intra <strong>SADC</strong> trade for most members (mainly with EU <strong>and</strong> US). <strong>The</strong> main<br />

determinant <strong>of</strong> growth in <strong>SADC</strong> appear, as expected, investment with labour, education <strong>and</strong><br />

financial development being valuable contributors as well.<br />

Table: Panel Data estimates<br />

Dependent variable output = log OUTPUT<br />

Variable R<strong>and</strong>om Effect<br />

Constant<br />

ivt<br />

estimates<br />

0.21<br />

(1.95)*<br />

0.53


edu<br />

l<br />

fd<br />

sadc<br />

nonsadc<br />

R 2<br />

Hausman test<br />

(2.41)***<br />

0.22<br />

(2.23)**<br />

0.28<br />

(2.02)*<br />

0.14<br />

(2.01)*<br />

0.16<br />

(2.25)<br />

0.31<br />

(2.27)***<br />

0.4<br />

Prob>Chi2=0.321<br />

*significant at 10%, ** significant at 5%, ***significant at 1%<br />

<strong>The</strong> small letters denotes variables in natural logarithmic <strong>and</strong> t values are in parentheses<br />

Dynamic Panel Data Regression.<br />

To incorporate the dynamic nature <strong>of</strong> economic growth into our model, we rewrite econometric<br />

equation as an AR (1) model in the following.<br />

y µ<br />

it − yit−1<br />

= α t + νyit−1<br />

+ βxit<br />

+ it<br />

(3)


where yit = the log <strong>of</strong> real GDP; xit= the vector <strong>of</strong> explanatory variables, that is x = [ivt, edu, l,<br />

fd,sadc,nonsadc] <strong>and</strong> αt = the period specific intercept terms to capture changes common to all<br />

sectors; μit = the time variant idiosyncratic error term.<br />

Equivalently, above equation can be written as<br />

y α ( ν y + βx<br />

+ µ<br />

(4)<br />

it = t + + 1)<br />

it−1<br />

We can also write the above in first differences<br />

∆ it = t + + 1)<br />

∆ it−1<br />

it<br />

it<br />

it<br />

y α ( ν y + β∆x<br />

+ ∆µ<br />

(5)<br />

it<br />

A problem <strong>of</strong> endogeneity might exist if yt-1 is endogeneous to the error terms through uit-1, <strong>and</strong> it<br />

will therefore be inappropriate to estimate the above specification by OLS. To overcome this<br />

problem <strong>of</strong> endogeneity, an instrumental variable needs to be used for Δyit-1. Two approaches,<br />

namely Instrumental Variable (IV, Anderson <strong>and</strong> Hsiao 1982) <strong>and</strong> two GMM estimators (Arellano<br />

<strong>and</strong> Bond’s 1991), first <strong>and</strong> second step respectively, can be used in this regard. We used the latter<br />

technique, as the IV approach leads to consistent but not necessary efficient estimates <strong>of</strong> the<br />

parameters (see Baltagi 1995). Moreover, the first step GMM estimator will be used since it has been<br />

shown to result in more reliable inferences. <strong>The</strong> asymptotic st<strong>and</strong>ards errors from the two step<br />

GMM estimator have been found to have a downward bias (Blundell <strong>and</strong> Bond 1998).<br />

<strong>The</strong> results from estimating equation (5), extended with a lag term, using the Arellano-Bond (1991)<br />

first step GMM estimator are contained in table 4. <strong>The</strong> various estimated equations passes all<br />

diagnosis test related to Sargan Test <strong>of</strong> Over-identifying restrictions <strong>and</strong> the Arellano-Bond test <strong>of</strong><br />

1 st order <strong>and</strong> 2 nd autocorrelation. Note that it has also been argued that since panel data techniques<br />

are employed, the issue <strong>of</strong> non-stationarity <strong>of</strong> the variables is less serious (Garcia Mila, McGuire <strong>and</strong><br />

Porter, 1996).<br />

Table 4: Dynamic Panel Data Estimation (First Step GMM estimator)<br />

Dependent variable y= log <strong>of</strong> Y<br />

Variable GMM estimates<br />

Constant 0.005


Δser,<br />

yt-1<br />

Δivt<br />

Δempt<br />

Δfd<br />

Δxpsadc<br />

Δxpnonsadc<br />

Diagnosis tests<br />

Sargan Test <strong>of</strong><br />

Overidentifying restrictions<br />

Arellano-Bond test <strong>of</strong> 1 st<br />

order autocorrelation<br />

Arellano-Bond test <strong>of</strong> 2 nd<br />

order autocorrelation<br />

*significant at 10%, ** significant at 5%, ***significant at 1%<br />

(2.29)**<br />

0.21<br />

(3.22)***<br />

0.19<br />

(1.99)*<br />

(0.1)<br />

(1.86)*<br />

0 15<br />

(2.16)**<br />

0.11<br />

(2.10)**<br />

0.04<br />

(1.76)*<br />

0.12**<br />

(2.14)**<br />

prob>chi2=0.34<br />

prob>chi2=0.264<br />

prob>chi2= 0.76<br />

<strong>The</strong> results from the dynamic panel analysis validate the preliminary results in general. We should<br />

highlight that the coefficient <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong>, that is trade to <strong>SADC</strong> member states, is positive, although<br />

small, but significant, suggesting that it has impacted significantly on the economic growth <strong>of</strong> the<br />

block. This is in line with the statistics we showed above <strong>and</strong> highlighted that trade within <strong>SADC</strong> is<br />

relatively higher than other major African block. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, trade to <strong>SADC</strong> countries is


observed to have been very influential to the economic development <strong>of</strong> the countries in the sample<br />

as judged by its coefficient. Recall from the literature above that Europe is the main importer <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>SADC</strong> products under the Cotonou agreement <strong>and</strong> Everything But Arms initiative. Investment,<br />

Education, Labour <strong>and</strong> Financial development report signs <strong>and</strong> magnitudes <strong>of</strong> elasticity as generally<br />

predicted by the literature.<br />

Interestingly the positive <strong>and</strong> significant coefficient <strong>of</strong> yt-1 from the table suggests that lagged income<br />

<strong>of</strong> the country contributes positively towards the current level <strong>of</strong> y confirming the existence <strong>of</strong><br />

dynamism <strong>and</strong> endogeineity in the modeling framework. This is consistent with recent works from<br />

Li <strong>and</strong> Liu (2005) <strong>and</strong> Seetanah (2007).<br />

Is <strong>SADC</strong> growth conducive for Mauritius?<br />

We also analyse is <strong>SADC</strong> as been economically beneficial to Mauritius for the period 1978-2010.<br />

Using the same model as previously described <strong>and</strong> augmented with an interactive dummy (<strong>SADC</strong><br />

trade <strong>and</strong> a dummy which takes the value <strong>of</strong> 0 before 1992 <strong>and</strong> 1 after the created on the <strong>SADC</strong><br />

block), we accounted for important feedback <strong>and</strong> endogeneity issues by adopting a VAR framework.<br />

However, before that we tested for the time series properties <strong>of</strong> our data series.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) (1979) <strong>and</strong> Phillips-Perron (PP) (1988) unit-root tests reveals<br />

that our variables are all integrated <strong>of</strong> order 1 (I(1)) <strong>and</strong> are thus stationary in first difference.<br />

Analysis <strong>of</strong> cointegration among the six variables was then undertaken using the Johansen Maximum<br />

Likelihood procedure <strong>and</strong> is based on a VAR <strong>of</strong> order 2, suggested by the Schwarz Bayesian<br />

criterion (SBC). Both the Maximum Eigenvalue test <strong>and</strong> the Trace test reveal the presence <strong>of</strong> one<br />

cointegrating vector.<br />

<strong>The</strong> estimated cointegrating vector, normalised on output, <strong>and</strong> the estimated adjustment parameters<br />

are presented in Table below<br />

Table : Estimates <strong>of</strong> long run parameter<br />

Variables<br />

β t-ratios


y<br />

ivt 0.68*** 3.34<br />

ser 0.27** 2.25<br />

lab 0.31* 1.88<br />

fd<br />

1<br />

0.36*** 2.34<br />

sadc 0.103* 1.82<br />

nonsadc 0.456** 2.12<br />

Sadc * Dum 0.215* 1.84<br />

*significant at 10%, ** significant at 5%, ***significant at 1%<br />

From the table above, <strong>of</strong> interest to us are the three last variables. Indeed it can be shown, as<br />

witnessed by the significant interactive dummy, that being in <strong>SADC</strong> has been growth beneficial for<br />

the country. It is noteworthy that probably even prior to <strong>SADC</strong> trade to these countries in aggregate<br />

had favourable growth benefits although to quite low extent, but it this could have accelerate to<br />

slightly greater extent with the formation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>RTA</strong>. However, trade to Non <strong>SADC</strong> countries is<br />

observed to have a much the greater output elasticity, revealing its relative higher importance as<br />

compared to <strong>SADC</strong> trade. As confirmed by previous studies, investment is the major driver <strong>of</strong><br />

growth with education <strong>and</strong> financial development being important ingredients as well.<br />

SUMMARY<br />

<strong>The</strong> paper investigated the relationship between growth <strong>and</strong> openness for the <strong>SADC</strong> <strong>RTA</strong> for the<br />

period 1995-2008. R<strong>and</strong>om effect estimates shows that <strong>SADC</strong> trade has been growth inductive but<br />

relative less as compared to no <strong>SADC</strong> trade. <strong>The</strong> results are confirmed using GMM panel estimates<br />

which moreover suggested the presence <strong>of</strong> dynamic in the system. <strong>The</strong> relatively low contribution is<br />

in line with the statistics <strong>and</strong> highlighted that trade within <strong>SADC</strong> is still relatively low. Trade to


NON<strong>SADC</strong> countries is observed to have been very influential to the economic development <strong>of</strong> the<br />

countries in the sample. One should bear in mind that Europe is the main importer <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong><br />

products under the Cotonou agreement <strong>and</strong> Everything But Arms initiative. Investment, Education,<br />

Labour <strong>and</strong> Financial development report signs <strong>and</strong> magnitudes <strong>of</strong> elasticity as generally predicted<br />

by the literature. Interestingly it appears that lagged income <strong>of</strong> the country contributes positively<br />

towards the current level <strong>of</strong> output confirming the existence <strong>of</strong> dynamism <strong>and</strong> endogeineity in the<br />

modeling framework.<br />

<strong>The</strong> time series study pertaining to the <strong>case</strong> <strong>of</strong> Mauritius revealed that <strong>SADC</strong> trade had a relatively<br />

small output elasticity as compared to NON <strong>SADC</strong> trade confirming that trade to the other non<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> partners, especially EU, is more influential in explaining the Mauritian economic growth.<br />

REFERENCES:<br />

Anderson, T, W & Hsio, C., 1982. Formulation <strong>and</strong> Estimation <strong>of</strong> dynamic Models using Panel<br />

Data’, Journal <strong>of</strong> Econometrics, 18: 47-82<br />

Arrelano, M <strong>and</strong> Bond, S., 1991. Some Tests <strong>of</strong> Specification for panel data: Monte Carlo Evidence<br />

<strong>and</strong> an application to employment equations, Review <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Studies :58:277-297<br />

Baltagi, B H (1995), Econometric Analysis <strong>of</strong> Panel Data, New York:John Wiley<br />

Barro, R.J. <strong>and</strong> Lee, J.-W., 1993. ‘International comparisons <strong>of</strong> educational attainment’ Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Monetary <strong>Economic</strong>s, 32, 363-394.<br />

Barro, R.J., 1991. ‘<strong>Economic</strong> growth in a cross-section <strong>of</strong> countries’. <strong>The</strong> Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Economic</strong>s, CVI, 2, 407-443.<br />

Benhabib, J. <strong>and</strong> Spiegel, M.M., 1994. ‘<strong>The</strong> role <strong>of</strong> human capital in economic development:<br />

evidence from aggregate cross-country data’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Monetary <strong>Economic</strong>s, 34, 143-173.<br />

Blundell <strong>and</strong> Bond., 1998. Initial conditions <strong>and</strong> Moments restrictions in dynamic panel data models,<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Econometrics 87:115-144<br />

Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D. <strong>and</strong> Weil, D.N., 1992, A contribution to the empirics <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> <strong>Economic</strong>s, CVI, 2, 407-437.


Rojid S. (2007), “Impact <strong>of</strong> COMESA Forming a Custom Union – A CGE Analysis”- presented at<br />

the Centre for the Study <strong>of</strong> African Economies (CSEA) Conference 2007 on <strong>Economic</strong> Development<br />

in Africa, University <strong>of</strong> Oxford, March 2007<br />

Seetanah B <strong>and</strong> Khadaroo J (2008), ‘Transport <strong>and</strong> economic performance: <strong>The</strong> <strong>case</strong> <strong>of</strong> Mauritius’,<br />

forthcoming in Journal <strong>of</strong> Transport <strong>Economic</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Policy<br />

Table 3: TimeLine <strong>and</strong> Achievements <strong>of</strong> the Southern African Development Community<br />

(<strong>SADC</strong>)<br />

Agreement Type Member Countries Date <strong>of</strong><br />

Entry in<br />

Force<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> FTA Angola, Botswana, DRC, Lesotho,<br />

Malawi , Mauritius, Mozambique,<br />

Namibia, Seychelles , South Africa,<br />

Swazil<strong>and</strong>, Tanzania, Zambia ,<br />

Zimbabwe<br />

Year Type <strong>of</strong> Achievement<br />

Several Trade Agreements with Third Parties<br />

GDP Per<br />

Capita<br />

(US$)<br />

Total<br />

Population<br />

1980 3, 152 233, 944, 179<br />

2008 <strong>The</strong> EU is currently negotiating an economic <strong>partnership</strong> agreement (EPA)<br />

Free Trade Area<br />

2008 Implementation <strong>of</strong> a Free Trade Area<br />

Trade Liberalisation Process<br />

2003 -<strong>SADC</strong> Member States committed themselves to a Regional Indicative Strategic<br />

Development Plan (RISDP) among whose goals <strong>and</strong> target dates is the attainment <strong>of</strong>


Future Developments<br />

Productive Sectors<br />

a Customs Union by 2010 <strong>and</strong> subsequently a Common Market by 2012.<br />

-Trade Protocol entered into force in January 2000. <strong>The</strong> Protocol is in line with<br />

<strong>SADC</strong>’s overall integration policies <strong>and</strong> strategies which seek to eliminate obstacles to<br />

the free movement <strong>of</strong> goods, services, capital <strong>and</strong> labour <strong>and</strong> to improve the region’s<br />

economic performance <strong>and</strong> international competitiveness. <strong>The</strong> gradual elimination <strong>of</strong><br />

tariff <strong>and</strong> non-tariff barriers will make it easier for traders to market their goods across<br />

borders, for manufacturers to source inputs regionally <strong>and</strong> add value to their products,<br />

<strong>and</strong> it will widen options for consumers to buy locally produced goods that are<br />

competitive in terms <strong>of</strong> quality <strong>and</strong> pricing<br />

- Category <strong>of</strong> Goods: A - Immediate reduction <strong>of</strong> duty to zero upon gazetting <strong>of</strong> tariff<br />

schedules by Member States; <strong>and</strong> On average 47% <strong>of</strong> all goods traded under this<br />

regime by August 2001. B - Gradual tariff reduction over 8 years; <strong>and</strong> 85% expected<br />

to trade at zero tariff by 2008. C - Sensitive products mainly in areas <strong>of</strong> security,<br />

health <strong>and</strong> safety; Constitute 15%; <strong>and</strong> Tariffs expected to be eliminated by 2012<br />

- A policy framework for technical regulations on st<strong>and</strong>ards, which is being put in<br />

place, takes into account the implementation <strong>of</strong> the World Trade Organization<br />

(WTO) Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade<br />

<strong>SADC</strong> is committed to develop closer economic cooperation between its Member<br />

States <strong>and</strong> this process is ongoing. <strong>The</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> objectives <strong>of</strong> a Free Trade Area by<br />

2008, Customs Union by 2010, Common Market by 2012, <strong>SADC</strong> Central Bank by<br />

2015, Monetary Union by 2016, <strong>and</strong> regional currency by 2018 - clearly all have an<br />

economic dimension.<br />

Mining – promotion <strong>of</strong> mining activities under <strong>SADC</strong>, investment <strong>and</strong> private sector<br />

participation


Table: <strong>SADC</strong> intra-regional exports(%share)<br />

Table : <strong>SADC</strong> intra-regional imports(%share)


Table: Value <strong>of</strong> top ten <strong>SADC</strong> exports for period 2000-2008(US $)<br />

Table: Value <strong>of</strong> top ten <strong>SADC</strong> exports for period 2000-2008 (US$ millions)


Table: Value <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> imports for the period 2000-2008 (US$ millions)<br />

Table: Total value <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> exports, 1980-2008 (US$ millions)


Source: UNCTAD 2009b<br />

Note: Countries included for each year are not clear<br />

Figure: Direction <strong>of</strong> <strong>SADC</strong> exports for period 1980-2008 (% by destination)


Source: UNCTAD 2009b<br />

Note: Countries included for each year are not clear<br />

Table: <strong>SADC</strong> ECONOMIC GROWTH RATE

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!