04.04.2014 Views

Income tax: the additional 50p rate ( PDF, 41 pages ... - Parliament

Income tax: the additional 50p rate ( PDF, 41 pages ... - Parliament

Income tax: the additional 50p rate ( PDF, 41 pages ... - Parliament

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Income</strong> <strong>tax</strong> : <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

Standard Note: SN249<br />

Last updated: 28 June 2013<br />

Author: Antony Seely<br />

Business & Transport Section<br />

In his 2009 Budget, <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Chancellor, Alistair Darling, announced several <strong>tax</strong> increases to<br />

“raise over £6 billion by 2012, to secure our economic future and to provide help for people<br />

now when <strong>the</strong>y need it most.” These changes included increases in <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s of indirect <strong>tax</strong>es<br />

– such as duties on road fuel and alcohol – for <strong>the</strong> current <strong>tax</strong> year, and changes to income<br />

<strong>tax</strong> from April 2010, including a new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on incomes above £150,000. The new <strong>50p</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> dominated reactions to <strong>the</strong> Budget, as many saw it as a significant change in <strong>the</strong> Labour<br />

Government’s approach to <strong>tax</strong>ing <strong>the</strong> wealthy. There was also much discussion as to<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> change would raise as much as <strong>the</strong> Government anticipated: £1.3bn in 2010/11,<br />

rising to £3.05bn in 2011/12. HM Revenue & Customs estimate that 236,000 individuals paid<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in 2010/11, compared to <strong>the</strong> total <strong>tax</strong>payer population of 31.3 million. 1<br />

The new Conservative-Liberal Democrat Government did not mention <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in <strong>the</strong><br />

agreement underpinning <strong>the</strong> Coalition, though it announced that <strong>the</strong> personal allowance<br />

would be increased in <strong>the</strong> forthcoming Budget “to help lower and middle income earners” as<br />

<strong>the</strong> first of a series of “real terms steps each year” toward setting <strong>the</strong> allowance at £10,000. 2<br />

In his first Budget speech on 22 June 2010, <strong>the</strong> Chancellor, George Osborne confirmed that<br />

<strong>the</strong> personal allowance would rise by £1,000 to £7,475 from April 2011, while <strong>the</strong> Budget<br />

report noted that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> would “remain in place for <strong>the</strong> time being.” 3 In his second<br />

Budget on 23 March 2011 <strong>the</strong> Chancellor made no changes to <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s of income <strong>tax</strong> for <strong>the</strong><br />

coming year but underlined his view that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> “would do lasting damage to our<br />

economy if it were to become permanent” and said he had asked HM Revenue & Customs to<br />

review “how much revenue it actually raises.” 4<br />

In his Budget on 21 March 2012 Mr Osborne announced that <strong>the</strong> department had found<br />

evidence of considerable ‘forestalling’ – <strong>tax</strong>payers shifting income into <strong>the</strong> previous <strong>tax</strong> year<br />

to avoid <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> “at a cost to <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payer of £1 billion.” He argued that “no Chancellor<br />

can justify a <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> that damages our economy and raises next to nothing” and so <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

would be cut to 45p from April 2013. 5 The department’s assessment of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was set<br />

1<br />

2<br />

3<br />

4<br />

5<br />

HC Deb 22 April 2009 c244; HC 451 March 2010 p140 (Table A11 : item l); HMRC, National Statistics:<br />

Number of individual income <strong>tax</strong>payers (Table 2.1), January 2013<br />

HM Government, The Coalition: our programme for government, 20 May 2010 p30. See also, <strong>Income</strong> <strong>tax</strong> :<br />

recent increases in <strong>the</strong> personal allowance, Library standard note SN6569, 25 March 2013<br />

HC Deb 22 June 2010 c179; HC 61 June 2010 p32 (para 1.97)<br />

HC Deb 23 March 2011 c957. See also, HC Deb 14 September 2011 c1191W<br />

HC Deb 21 March 2012 cc805-6. The Government confirmed that <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> would be 45% for<br />

2013/14 in <strong>the</strong> 2013 Budget (HC 1033, March 2013 para 1.202-3).<br />

This information is provided to Members of <strong>Parliament</strong> in support of <strong>the</strong>ir parliamentary duties and is not intended<br />

to address <strong>the</strong> specific circumstances of any particular individual. It should not be relied upon as being up to date;<br />

<strong>the</strong> law or policies may have changed since it was last updated; and it should not be relied upon as legal or<br />

professional advice or as a substitute for it. A suitably qualified professional should be consulted if specific advice<br />

or information is required.<br />

This information is provided subject to our general terms and conditions which are available online or may be<br />

provided on request in hard copy. Authors are available to discuss <strong>the</strong> content of this briefing with Members and<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir staff, but not with <strong>the</strong> general public


out in a detailed report, which estimated that <strong>the</strong> cost of cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> to 45p would be only<br />

£100m by 2014/15, given <strong>the</strong> anticipated response by <strong>tax</strong>payers to this change. 6<br />

This note discusses <strong>the</strong> background to <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, <strong>the</strong> debate <strong>the</strong>re has been, as to its<br />

political significance and its economic impact, before looking at <strong>the</strong> Government’s decision to<br />

cut this <strong>rate</strong> to 45p from April 2013.<br />

Contents<br />

1 Pre-Budget Report 2008 – <strong>the</strong> 45p <strong>rate</strong> 2<br />

2 Budget 2009 – <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> 7<br />

3 First responses to <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> 9<br />

4 Debate on <strong>the</strong> potential yield of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> 13<br />

5 The 2010 Budget 16<br />

6 The Coalition Government’s approach 18<br />

7 The 2012 Budget : cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> to 45p 24<br />

Appendix: Discussion of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in <strong>the</strong> Mirrlees Review 40<br />

1 Pre-Budget Report 2008 – <strong>the</strong> 45p <strong>rate</strong><br />

In his Pre-Budget statement on 24 November 2008, <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Chancellor, Alistair Darling,<br />

announced a number of measures to “raise revenue in future years”; among <strong>the</strong> options to<br />

raise funds, Mr Darling suggested that <strong>the</strong> ones he had chosen were “<strong>the</strong> fairest and affect<br />

those who have done best out of <strong>the</strong> growth of <strong>the</strong> past decade”:<br />

Today’s pre-Budget report shows that <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> burden, as a share of gross domestic<br />

product, will fall from 36.3 per cent. last year to 35 per cent. in 2011-12. Against that<br />

background, I propose from April 2011 to increase by ½ per cent. all <strong>rate</strong>s of national<br />

insurance contributions for both employees and employers.<br />

To ensure that <strong>the</strong> increase does not fall on those on low or modest incomes, I have<br />

decided, at <strong>the</strong> same time, to raise <strong>the</strong> starting point for national insurance to align it<br />

with that for income <strong>tax</strong>, so that no one on under £20,000 will pay any more national<br />

insurance contributions as a result. Secondly, those with <strong>the</strong> highest incomes have<br />

seen <strong>the</strong>ir earnings almost double since 1996, so—again from April 2011—I intend,<br />

only on income over £150,000, to introduce a new <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> of 45 per cent.<br />

This higher <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> will affect only <strong>the</strong> top 1 per cent. of incomes.<br />

I also intend to withdraw <strong>the</strong> long-standing anomaly of <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> system under<br />

which <strong>the</strong> personal allowance is worth twice as much to higher-<strong>rate</strong> than to basic-<strong>rate</strong><br />

6<br />

HMRC, The Exchequer effect of <strong>the</strong> 50 per cent <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong>, March 2012 pp 48-53. The<br />

report estimated that <strong>the</strong> ‘static cost’ of this <strong>tax</strong> cut, with no allowance for any behavioural response, would be<br />

£3.35 billion in 2014/15. See also, Budget 2013, HC 1033, March 2013 p66 (Table 2.2 – item t)<br />

2


<strong>tax</strong>payers. Again, I will protect those on middle incomes; this will affect only those<br />

earning over £100,000—that is, <strong>the</strong> top 2 per cent. So from April 2010, those with<br />

incomes between £100,000 and £140,000 will see <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong>ir personal<br />

allowance reduced, so that <strong>the</strong>y get <strong>the</strong> same benefit as basic-<strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payers. For<br />

people with incomes above £140,000, I will withdraw <strong>the</strong> full value of that personal<br />

allowance. 7<br />

The Pre-Budget Report gave more details on each of <strong>the</strong>se changes:<br />

• The income <strong>tax</strong> personal allowance will be restricted for those with incomes over<br />

£100,000 – <strong>the</strong> two per cent of people with <strong>the</strong> highest incomes – from April 2010,<br />

when <strong>the</strong> economy is forecast to be growing. From that level of income, <strong>the</strong><br />

personal allowance will be reduced at a <strong>rate</strong> of £1 of allowance lost for every £2 of<br />

income over that level until it is halved in value. At this value, <strong>the</strong> personal<br />

allowance will be worth <strong>the</strong> same as for a basic <strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payer. From £140,000 of<br />

income, <strong>the</strong> remaining allowance will be completely withdrawn at <strong>the</strong> same<br />

withdrawal <strong>rate</strong>, so that people with <strong>the</strong> very highest incomes do not benefit from<br />

<strong>the</strong> personal allowance;<br />

• A new <strong>additional</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> of 45 per cent (and 37.5 per cent for<br />

dividend income) for those with incomes above £150,000 from April 2011. This will<br />

ensure that people with <strong>the</strong> very highest individual incomes pay a greater share of<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir income in <strong>tax</strong>; and<br />

• A 0.5 per cent increase in <strong>the</strong> employee, employer and self-employed <strong>rate</strong>s of NICs<br />

from April 2011, alongside an increase above indexation in <strong>the</strong> point at which<br />

individuals start to pay NICs – known as <strong>the</strong> primary threshold – so that it is aligned<br />

with <strong>the</strong> personal allowance. This will ensure that <strong>the</strong> fiscal consolidation is broad<br />

based, without affecting those over state pension age, who do not pay NICs. These<br />

changes will be introduced from 2011, when <strong>the</strong> economy is forecast to be growing<br />

above trend <strong>rate</strong>s and real incomes are growing strongly.<br />

The measures above mean that people with incomes below £40,000 will not pay more<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> and NICs in April 2011 than in April 2008. People with incomes between<br />

£40,000 and £100,000 a year will pay slightly more income <strong>tax</strong> and NICs, around £3 a<br />

week on average. Those with incomes between £100,000 and £140,000 will pay<br />

around £22 a week more on average in income <strong>tax</strong> and NICs, while those between<br />

£140,000 and £200,000 will pay on average £61 a week, and progressively more as<br />

income rises. 8<br />

The report estimated that introducing <strong>the</strong> 45% <strong>rate</strong> – and raising <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on trusts to 45%<br />

- would raise £670m in 2011/12. Restricting <strong>the</strong> personal allowance for individuals with<br />

incomes over £100,000 would raise £1.32bn in <strong>the</strong> same year. By contrast, increasing <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong>s of NI by ½ a percentage point on employees, employers and <strong>the</strong> self-employed would<br />

raise an estimated £5.4bn in 2011/12; raising <strong>the</strong> NI primary threshold, to align it with <strong>the</strong><br />

personal allowance would cost £1.6bn. 9<br />

7<br />

8<br />

9<br />

HC Deb 24 November 2008 c496<br />

Cm 7484 November 2008 p85<br />

Cm 7484 November 2008 p194 (Table B5). The yield from both <strong>the</strong> 45% <strong>rate</strong> and <strong>the</strong> withdrawal of <strong>the</strong><br />

personal allowance would be lagged due to self-assessment, and <strong>the</strong> Government estimated that for 2011/12<br />

onwards, each measure would raise £1.6bn (Table B5 – footnote 3).<br />

3


Much of <strong>the</strong> reaction to <strong>the</strong> PBR focused on <strong>the</strong> Chancellor’s announcement of a temporary<br />

cut in VAT, as <strong>the</strong> centrepiece of a fiscal stimulus programme for <strong>the</strong> coming year. 10 That<br />

said, Robert Peston, <strong>the</strong> BBC’s business editor, suggested that <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> proposals<br />

were “<strong>the</strong> first seriously redistributive <strong>tax</strong> changes since <strong>the</strong> 1970s … in a way, this Labour<br />

government has ditched <strong>the</strong> cornerstone of Thatcherism, which is that those on highest<br />

earnings will create wealth for <strong>the</strong> benefit of all of us if <strong>the</strong>y’re allowance to keep as much as<br />

possible of <strong>the</strong>ir respective incomes.” 11<br />

Robert Chote, <strong>the</strong>n director of <strong>the</strong> Institute for Fiscal Studies (IFS), argued that <strong>the</strong> decision<br />

to withdraw <strong>the</strong> personal allowance for wealthier <strong>tax</strong>payers was as important a change as <strong>the</strong><br />

new 45p <strong>rate</strong>, especially from <strong>the</strong> perspective of <strong>the</strong> incentives created by <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> structure<br />

for people to change <strong>the</strong>ir behaviour:<br />

The introduction of <strong>the</strong> new 45p income <strong>tax</strong> band on incomes above £150,000<br />

understandably caught everyone’s attention, being <strong>the</strong> first increase in <strong>the</strong> highest<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> band since 1974. The Treasury estimates that this will raise £1.6 billion in a<br />

full year, although this has to be a very tentative guess. If more of <strong>the</strong>se people declare<br />

less <strong>tax</strong>able income, put more into <strong>the</strong>ir pensions, increase charitable giving or engage<br />

in avoidance than <strong>the</strong> Treasury expects <strong>the</strong>n it may raise less than it hopes.<br />

Almost as important in revenue terms – and much less obvious to <strong>the</strong> naked eye – is<br />

<strong>the</strong> impact of taking away <strong>the</strong> personal income <strong>tax</strong> allowance for people on high<br />

incomes. This in effect creates two new 60% income <strong>tax</strong> bands for incomes between<br />

£100,000 and £106,450 and between £140,000 and £146,450 for no obvious economic<br />

rationale. This will create a very powerful incentive for people with incomes within<br />

<strong>the</strong>se bands to increase <strong>the</strong>ir pension contributions until <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong>able incomes fall to<br />

<strong>the</strong> bottom of <strong>the</strong> bands. 12<br />

In an editorial <strong>the</strong> Financial Times noted <strong>the</strong> incentives <strong>the</strong> new higher <strong>rate</strong> would create,<br />

going on to argue that, “<strong>the</strong>re is a broader question of uncertainty too. After Labour won<br />

three elections promising not to increase <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong>, plans for <strong>the</strong> first such<br />

hike since 1974 prompts fears of fur<strong>the</strong>r rises. Now that <strong>the</strong> commitment to stop at 40 per<br />

cent has gone, why believe 45 per cent will be a sticking point?” 13 The Institute of Chartered<br />

Accountants were strongly critical of <strong>the</strong> proposal, in <strong>the</strong>ir submission to <strong>the</strong> Treasury<br />

Committee on <strong>the</strong> PBR:<br />

The withdrawal of personal allowances at one pound for every two pounds of income<br />

creates an effective <strong>additional</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of 20% in addition to <strong>the</strong> 40% income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>—<br />

ie an effective <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of 60% at income levels just above £100,000 and £140,000.<br />

This effect is demonst<strong>rate</strong>d by <strong>the</strong> comparison of “Case A” and “Case B” in Table 1. as<br />

follows:<br />

10<br />

11<br />

12<br />

13<br />

For example, <strong>the</strong> Treasury Committee’s report on <strong>the</strong> PBR did not discuss any of <strong>the</strong>se direct <strong>tax</strong> changes in<br />

detail (Second report: Pre-Budget Report 2008, 28 January 2009 HC 27 2008-09).<br />

“End of Thatcher’s <strong>tax</strong> incentives”, Peston’s Picks blog – BBC newsite, 24 November 2008<br />

Opening remarks for post-PBR briefing – Robert Chote, IFS 25 November 2008 p3<br />

“Leader: Fussy and feeble income <strong>tax</strong> rises”, Financial Times, 27 November 2008<br />

4


This example demonst<strong>rate</strong>s that income of £100 has resulted in a fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>tax</strong> charge of<br />

£60, an effective marginal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of 60% … <strong>the</strong> proposals introduce considerable<br />

complexity into <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> system and associated <strong>tax</strong> calculations and result in two<br />

effective marginal <strong>rate</strong>s of <strong>tax</strong> of 61%. This increased complexity contrasts with <strong>the</strong><br />

announcements in 2007 PBR designed to simplify <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> system, in particular <strong>the</strong><br />

introduction of a flat-<strong>rate</strong> of Capital gains Tax (CGT). The difference in <strong>rate</strong> between<br />

<strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> (45%) and CGT (18%) is now 27%, fur<strong>the</strong>r increasing <strong>the</strong><br />

incentive to ensure that returns are received by way of capital gains ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

income. 14<br />

By contrast, in <strong>the</strong>ir evidence to <strong>the</strong> Committee, <strong>the</strong> TUC, while concerned about <strong>the</strong> rise in<br />

NICs, argued that restricting <strong>the</strong> personal allowance was “a very positive move, which<br />

responds to a point made by <strong>the</strong> TUC for some time now that <strong>the</strong> progressive nature of our<br />

<strong>tax</strong> system is undermined by excessive use of reliefs and allowances by <strong>the</strong> very wealthy.” 15<br />

In <strong>the</strong>ir Green Budget published in January 2009, <strong>the</strong> IFS noted that <strong>the</strong>re were considerable<br />

difficulties in making accu<strong>rate</strong> predictions as to <strong>the</strong> amounts of money <strong>the</strong>se changes could<br />

raise, since it “requires accu<strong>rate</strong> information about income growth at <strong>the</strong> top of <strong>the</strong> income<br />

distribution, <strong>the</strong> shape of <strong>the</strong> income distribution and <strong>the</strong> responsiveness of <strong>the</strong> very rich to<br />

changes in <strong>the</strong>ir marginal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s. All of <strong>the</strong>se are subject to a high degree of uncertainty.” 16<br />

The Institute was also critical of <strong>the</strong> impact that withdrawing <strong>the</strong> personal allowance would<br />

have on <strong>the</strong> schedule of marginal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s; <strong>the</strong> two narrow income bands over which <strong>the</strong><br />

allowance was withdrawn, <strong>the</strong> effective marginal <strong>rate</strong>, expressed as a percentage of<br />

employer cost, would be 66%:<br />

This is calculated by adding toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, employees’ NI <strong>rate</strong> and<br />

employers’ NI <strong>rate</strong> and dividing by 1 plus <strong>the</strong> employers’ NI <strong>rate</strong>, in this case (0.45 +<br />

0.015 + 0.133)/1.133. This is because increasing gross earnings by £1 leads to<br />

<strong>additional</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> liability of 45p, <strong>additional</strong> employees’ NICs of 1.5p and <strong>additional</strong><br />

employers’ NICs of 13.3p and <strong>the</strong> total cost to <strong>the</strong> employer has increased by £1.133.<br />

This <strong>the</strong>refore gives <strong>the</strong> proportion of an extra pound that an employer spends<br />

employing someone that is taken in income … It is possible that an optimal <strong>tax</strong><br />

schedule does involve a lower marginal <strong>rate</strong> at <strong>the</strong> very top of <strong>the</strong> income distribution<br />

than slightly lower down … This might be <strong>the</strong> case if those at <strong>the</strong> very top of <strong>the</strong><br />

income distribution were more responses to changes in <strong>the</strong>ir marginal effective <strong>rate</strong> ....<br />

However …. it seems unlikely that it would figure <strong>the</strong> two large spikes in <strong>the</strong> marginal<br />

17<br />

<strong>rate</strong> schedule that <strong>the</strong> government is proposing.<br />

14<br />

15<br />

16<br />

17<br />

HC 27 2008-09 Ev81-2<br />

HC 27 2008-09 Ev88<br />

Green Budget 2009, January 2009 p213<br />

Green Budget 2009, January 2009 p216, 218, 226<br />

5


Just prior to <strong>the</strong> 2009 Budget, <strong>the</strong> IFS published a follow-up report on <strong>the</strong> potential response<br />

of <strong>tax</strong>payers, drawing on correspondence with <strong>the</strong> department, and earlier research on <strong>the</strong><br />

responses of wealthy <strong>tax</strong>payers when <strong>the</strong> highest income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s were last changed in <strong>the</strong><br />

late 1980s. The research was highly technical, but, very briefly, <strong>the</strong> authors looked at <strong>the</strong><br />

relationship between marginal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s, and <strong>the</strong> income share of <strong>the</strong> richest 1% of adults,<br />

over <strong>the</strong> period 1962-2003. 18 As <strong>the</strong>y observe, <strong>the</strong> UK experienced a dramatic drop in <strong>the</strong><br />

marginal effective <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s (METRs) 19 on <strong>the</strong> highest incomes during <strong>the</strong> 1980s, which<br />

makes it a particularly valuable period to study: “up to 1978, <strong>the</strong> top METR on earnings was<br />

83%. Under <strong>the</strong> Thatcher administrations, <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> dropped to 60% in 1979, and <strong>the</strong>n<br />

dropped fur<strong>the</strong>r to 40% in 1988.” Assuming an underlying consistency in <strong>the</strong> way individuals<br />

and firms respond to marginal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s, <strong>the</strong> authors go on to suggest that raising <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s<br />

on <strong>the</strong> highest earners would be unlikely to provide an effective method of raising revenue:<br />

The way that incomes have responded to <strong>the</strong> large changes in top marginal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s<br />

over <strong>the</strong> past 40 years suggests that if <strong>the</strong> richest 1% see a 1% fall in <strong>the</strong> proportion of<br />

each <strong>additional</strong> pound of earnings that is left after <strong>tax</strong>, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> income <strong>the</strong>y report will<br />

rise by less than half that - only 0.46%. [The term used for this is <strong>tax</strong>able income<br />

elasticity.] Although a tentative estimate, this suggests that <strong>the</strong> government would<br />

maximise <strong>the</strong> revenue it collects by imposing an overall marginal <strong>rate</strong> on <strong>the</strong> highest<br />

earners of 56.6%, very close to <strong>the</strong> 53.0% currently charged in <strong>the</strong> UK (including<br />

income <strong>tax</strong>, national insurance contributions and indirect <strong>tax</strong>es). So <strong>the</strong>re does not<br />

seem a powerful case for increasing <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on <strong>the</strong> very highest earners,<br />

even on redistributive grounds - it would not gene<strong>rate</strong> much if any extra revenue to<br />

transfer to <strong>the</strong> less well off. 20<br />

It is worth adding that <strong>the</strong> authors emphasized that <strong>the</strong>ir estimates of this behavioural<br />

response was subject to a great deal of uncertainty – from <strong>the</strong> paucity of <strong>the</strong> data <strong>the</strong>y used,<br />

and <strong>the</strong> fact that this period in <strong>the</strong> 1980s, not only was <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> was falling, but<br />

income inequality was increasing as well. As a consequence, this analysis might “confuse<br />

responses to <strong>the</strong> policy with any underlying factor increasing income inequality, and this<br />

might mean <strong>the</strong> estimated elasticity is too high.” 21<br />

In <strong>the</strong> course of <strong>the</strong>ir work, <strong>the</strong> IFS made an FOI request to <strong>the</strong> Treasury about its<br />

calculations in <strong>the</strong> 2008 PBR, about <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>: in brief, <strong>the</strong> department<br />

used a figure for <strong>tax</strong>able income elasticity set at 0.35% - ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> IFS’ figure of<br />

0.46%. 22 During <strong>the</strong> Committee proceedings of <strong>the</strong> Finance Bill <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Financial Secretary<br />

Stephen Timms stated that in doing so, Treasury officials had looked at <strong>the</strong> work on <strong>the</strong> UK<br />

experience in <strong>the</strong> 1980s, and “academic evidence available for a range of o<strong>the</strong>r countries,<br />

<strong>the</strong> USA in particular.” He went on to argue that two changes in <strong>the</strong> Government’s approach<br />

to <strong>tax</strong> avoidance in <strong>the</strong> last few years that would have been “likely to have had a downward<br />

impact on <strong>tax</strong>able income elasticity in <strong>the</strong> UK;” 23 namely,<br />

18<br />

19<br />

20<br />

21<br />

22<br />

23<br />

Mike Brewer, et al., Means-testing and <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s on earnings: Prepared for <strong>the</strong> Report of a Commission on<br />

Reforming <strong>the</strong> Tax System for <strong>the</strong> 21st Century, April 2008<br />

The marginal effective <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> (METR) measures how much of a small rise in gross earnings is lost to<br />

payments of <strong>tax</strong> and reduced entitlements to benefits.<br />

Means-testing and <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s on earnings … April 2008 p15, p1<br />

Mike Brewer & James Browne, Can more revenue be raised by increasing income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s for <strong>the</strong> very rich?,<br />

IFS briefing note BN84, April 2009 p6<br />

IFS briefing note BN84, April 2009 p7<br />

Public Bill Committee (Finance Bill) 21 May 2009 cc89-90<br />

6


• The ‘Disclosure Regime’, introduced in <strong>the</strong> 2004 Budget: a scheme which requires<br />

accountancy firms and o<strong>the</strong>r practitioners to disclose any new direct <strong>tax</strong> avoidance<br />

schemes to <strong>the</strong> revenue departments. 24<br />

• The threat of retrospective legislation made by <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Paymaster General, Dawn<br />

Primarolo, in <strong>the</strong> 2004 PBR: that to “deal with any arrangements that emerge in future<br />

designed to frust<strong>rate</strong> our intention that employers and employees should pay <strong>the</strong><br />

proper amount of <strong>tax</strong> and National Insurance contributions (NICs) on <strong>the</strong> rewards of<br />

employment”, <strong>the</strong> Government would be willing to introduce legislation to counter any<br />

avoidance scheme that subsequently came to light, “where necessary” with effect<br />

from <strong>the</strong> date of <strong>the</strong> PBR. 25<br />

The IFS re-examined <strong>the</strong> department’s estimates in a chapter on <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in <strong>the</strong>ir 2012<br />

Green Budget; 26 <strong>the</strong> authors’ conclusions are discussed below, but it is worth noting two<br />

points that underline <strong>the</strong> uncertainty surrounding <strong>the</strong>se numbers: first, no allowance is made<br />

by <strong>the</strong> Treasury for any impact on revenues from indirect <strong>tax</strong>es – as, say, <strong>the</strong> responses of<br />

those affected by <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> results in a drop in <strong>the</strong>ir expenditure, and thus a drop <strong>the</strong><br />

Exchequer’s VAT receipts. Second, <strong>the</strong> Treasury do not factor in any possible ‘fiscal<br />

externalities’ from behavioural responses, counteracting <strong>the</strong> first of <strong>the</strong>se effects. Efforts by<br />

<strong>tax</strong>payers to postpone paying <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> might mean more <strong>tax</strong> was collected at a later<br />

date; decisions to take remuneration in <strong>the</strong> form of capital ra<strong>the</strong>r than income might boost<br />

receipts from capital gains <strong>tax</strong>. All told, as <strong>the</strong> IFS observe, “<strong>the</strong> truth is that <strong>the</strong>re remains a<br />

great deal of uncertainty over <strong>the</strong> revenue-maximising top income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>.” 27<br />

2 Budget 2009 – <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

In his Budget speech on 22 April 2009 <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Chancellor, Alistair Darling announced two<br />

important revisions to his earlier proposals for income <strong>tax</strong> increases on <strong>the</strong> very rich:<br />

I am not proposing to increase <strong>tax</strong>es on income for this year. However, as <strong>the</strong><br />

economy recovers and wages start to grow again, it is right that we take <strong>additional</strong><br />

steps. I believe that it is fair that those who have gained <strong>the</strong> most should contribute<br />

more. Only those with incomes over £100,000 a year—or 2 per cent. of <strong>the</strong><br />

population—will be affected.<br />

In November, I announced a new <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> of 45 per cent. on incomes above<br />

£150,000—<strong>the</strong> top 1 per cent. of <strong>tax</strong>payers. In order to help pay for <strong>additional</strong> support<br />

for people now and to invest in <strong>the</strong> future, I have decided that <strong>the</strong> new <strong>rate</strong> will be 50<br />

per cent., and will come in from April next year—a year earlier. In November, I also<br />

announced that I was reducing personal allowances for <strong>the</strong> very highest earners with<br />

incomes over £100,000. These allowances are worth twice as much as those of basic<br />

<strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payers. I have now decided to withdraw fully <strong>the</strong> benefit of that allowance for<br />

24<br />

25<br />

26<br />

27<br />

Similar rules were introduced for businesses that used or marketed VAT avoidance schemes. The Regime<br />

has been extended to National Insurance contributions, stamp duty land <strong>tax</strong> & inheritance <strong>tax</strong>. HMRC’s site<br />

gives full details of <strong>the</strong> regime at: http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/aiu/index.htm<br />

HC Deb 2 December 2004 cc44-6WS. Ano<strong>the</strong>r Library standard note discusses <strong>the</strong>se initiatives in more detail:<br />

Tax avoidance: a General Anti-Avoidance Rule (GAAR) – background history, SN2956, 26 July 2012.<br />

“Chapter 9: <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>: what is known and what will be known?”, in, The IFS 2012 Green Budget,<br />

February 2012 pp 180-196.<br />

op.cit. p193<br />

7


those with incomes over £100,000 from next April. These measures are necessary to<br />

build our recovery and secure our country’s economic future. 28<br />

Details of <strong>the</strong> new income <strong>tax</strong> structure from 2010 were set out in a Budget note:<br />

For 2009-10, <strong>the</strong>re are two main <strong>rate</strong>s of income <strong>tax</strong>. The 20 per cent basic <strong>rate</strong> of<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> applies to <strong>tax</strong>able income up to £37,400. The 40 per cent higher <strong>rate</strong><br />

applies to <strong>tax</strong>able income above £37,400. From April 2010, a 50 per cent <strong>additional</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> will apply to <strong>tax</strong>able income above £150,000.<br />

From 2010-11 <strong>the</strong>re will be three <strong>rate</strong>s of <strong>tax</strong> for dividends. Dividends o<strong>the</strong>rwise<br />

<strong>tax</strong>able at <strong>the</strong> 20 per cent basic <strong>rate</strong> will continue to be <strong>tax</strong>able at <strong>the</strong> 10 per cent<br />

dividend ordinary <strong>rate</strong> and dividends o<strong>the</strong>rwise <strong>tax</strong>able at <strong>the</strong> 40 per cent higher <strong>rate</strong><br />

will continue to be <strong>tax</strong>able at <strong>the</strong> 32.5 per cent dividend upper <strong>rate</strong>. Dividends<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise <strong>tax</strong>able at <strong>the</strong> new 50 per cent <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> will be <strong>tax</strong>able at a new 42.5<br />

per cent dividend <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. From 2010-11, <strong>the</strong> dividend trust <strong>rate</strong> will be<br />

increased from 32.5 per cent to 42.5 per cent and <strong>the</strong> trust <strong>rate</strong> will be increased from<br />

40 per cent to 50 per cent.<br />

The basic personal allowance provides an amount of <strong>tax</strong> free income. All individuals<br />

entitled to <strong>the</strong> basic personal allowance receive <strong>the</strong> same amount. From 2010-11, <strong>the</strong><br />

basic personal allowance will be subject to a single income limit of £100,000. Where an<br />

individual’s adjusted net income … is below or equal to <strong>the</strong> £100,000 limit, <strong>the</strong>y will<br />

continue to be entitled to <strong>the</strong> full amount of <strong>the</strong> basic personal allowance.<br />

From 2010-11, where an individual’s adjusted net income is above <strong>the</strong> income limit of<br />

£100,000, <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>the</strong> allowance will be reduced by £1 for every £2 above <strong>the</strong><br />

income limit. The personal allowance will be reduced to nil from this income limit<br />

instead of <strong>the</strong> two-stage reduction announced at <strong>the</strong> Pre-Budget Report.<br />

“Adjusted net income” is <strong>the</strong> measure of an individual’s income that is used for <strong>the</strong><br />

calculation of <strong>the</strong> existing income-related reductions to personal allowances those<br />

aged between 65 and 74, and for those aged 75 and over. Adjusted net income is<br />

calculated in a series of steps. The starting point is “net income” which is <strong>the</strong> total of<br />

<strong>the</strong> individual’s income subject to income <strong>tax</strong> less specified deductions, <strong>the</strong> most<br />

important of which are trading losses and payments made gross to pension schemes.<br />

This net income is <strong>the</strong>n reduced by <strong>the</strong> grossed-up amount of <strong>the</strong> individual’s Gift Aid<br />

contributions and <strong>the</strong> grossed-up amount of <strong>the</strong> individual’s pension contributions<br />

which have received <strong>tax</strong> relief at source. The final step is to add back any relief for<br />

payments to trade unions or police organisations deducted in arriving at <strong>the</strong> individual’s<br />

net income. The result is <strong>the</strong> individual’s adjusted net income. 29<br />

The department also published a number of worked examples to show how <strong>the</strong> new 50%<br />

<strong>rate</strong>, and <strong>the</strong> tapering of <strong>the</strong> personal allowances, would work in practice. 30<br />

At this time it was estimated that <strong>the</strong> new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on earnings above £150,000 would raise<br />

£2.5bn by 2011/12, and <strong>the</strong> withdrawal of <strong>the</strong> personal allowance from individuals with<br />

28<br />

29<br />

30<br />

HC Deb 22 April 2009 c244<br />

HM Revenue & Customs Budget Note BN01, 22 April 2009. Emphasis added.<br />

The examples used <strong>the</strong> 2009/10 figure of personal allowance and basic <strong>rate</strong> band; as it transpired both were<br />

frozen for <strong>the</strong> 2010/11 year. (HM Revenue & Customs, Additional Rate of <strong>Income</strong> Tax and <strong>Income</strong> Related<br />

Reduction of <strong>the</strong> Personal Allowance from 2010 -11 Supplementary Note and Examples, 23 April 2009).<br />

8


incomes above £100,000 would raise £1.4bn in <strong>the</strong> same year. 31 At <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> 2010<br />

Budget <strong>the</strong>se estimates were revised upward: to £3.1bn, and £1.47bn, respectively. 32<br />

The one o<strong>the</strong>r measure in <strong>the</strong> 2009 Budget estimated to raise equivalent sums was <strong>the</strong><br />

proposal to increase <strong>the</strong> main duties on road fuel: first, by 2p a litre on 1 September 2008,<br />

and <strong>the</strong>n, by 1p per litre in real terms on 1 April each year from 2010-3. It was estimated that<br />

<strong>the</strong>se increases would raise £1.75bn by 2011/12. By way of comparison, at this time it was<br />

estimated that changing <strong>the</strong> basic <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> by 1p would raise £3.9bn in 2011/12. 33<br />

Finally, <strong>the</strong> Chancellor also announced proposals to restrict higher <strong>rate</strong> relief on pension<br />

contributions made by individuals with incomes over £150,000 from April 2011. One reason<br />

to do this was to counteract <strong>the</strong> impact that <strong>the</strong> new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> would have on <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>tax</strong><br />

relief on contributions for those liable to <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. The method chosen by Mr<br />

Darling to restrict relief was strongly criticized by <strong>the</strong> pensions industry, and <strong>the</strong> Coalition<br />

Government introduced provisions in <strong>the</strong> Finance Act 2011 to restrict relief in a simpler<br />

fashion while raising an equivalent sum of money. 34<br />

3 First responses to <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

The Chancellor’s announcement of a new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> dominated initial reactions to <strong>the</strong> Budget.<br />

Many commentators argued this marked a significant change in <strong>the</strong> Labour Government’s<br />

approach to personal <strong>tax</strong>ation; that said, while <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> had an important symbolic value,<br />

<strong>the</strong> projected revenues from this measure were small, in <strong>the</strong> context of <strong>the</strong> ballooning size of<br />

<strong>the</strong> public deficit. The Guardian’s economics editor, Larry Elliott, put it this way:<br />

Having told us a year ago that <strong>the</strong> budget deficit would be £38bn in 2009-10, Darling<br />

revised <strong>the</strong> figure up to £118bn in <strong>the</strong> pre-budget report in November and to £175bn<br />

yesterday. That represents a deterioration of £137bn. In total, <strong>the</strong> new 50% <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>,<br />

scrapping <strong>tax</strong> allowances and restricting <strong>tax</strong> relief on pensions will raise, at best, £7bn.<br />

Bringing <strong>the</strong> deficit down to more manageable levels will require years of implausibly<br />

high growth, a squeeze on public spending even more severe than during <strong>the</strong> Thatcher<br />

years and, after <strong>the</strong> election, widespread <strong>tax</strong> increases. 35<br />

An editorial in <strong>the</strong> paper commented that <strong>the</strong>se measures were “a commendable attempt to<br />

share <strong>the</strong> pain – but it will not do much to plug <strong>the</strong> yawning gap in <strong>the</strong> public finances, seeing<br />

as it was not combined with measures on property or capital.” 36 In <strong>the</strong> Independent, Hamish<br />

McRae said, “leaving aside <strong>the</strong> breaking of <strong>the</strong> New Labour covenant on <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s, it is plain<br />

stupid to make a change that brings in less revenue, not more. If you need more revenue<br />

you have to be honest and acknowledge that it must come from higher basic <strong>rate</strong> income <strong>tax</strong><br />

and higher VAT.” 37 Similarly <strong>the</strong> Economist observed that <strong>the</strong> changes “will irritate <strong>the</strong> 1-2%<br />

31<br />

32<br />

33<br />

34<br />

35<br />

36<br />

37<br />

These estimates took into account <strong>the</strong> revenue raised from <strong>the</strong> 2008 PBR proposals, along with <strong>the</strong> Budget<br />

2009 changes: HC 407 April 2009 pp153-4 (Tables A1 & A2; also Table A1 – footnotes 2&3).<br />

Budget 2010 HC 451 March 2010 p140. These estimates were also given in a written answer several months<br />

later on <strong>the</strong> projected yield of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> (HC Deb 24 November 2010 c367W).<br />

HMRC, National Statistics: Table 1.6 (Direct effects of illustrative <strong>tax</strong> changes), December 2011<br />

For details see, Restricting pension <strong>tax</strong> relief, Library standard note SN5901, 17 December 2012.<br />

“Labour’s leaving present”, Guardian, 23 April 2009<br />

“Editorial: Budget – cost of a crisis”, Guardian, 23 April 2009<br />

“Age of New Labour draws to a close with deceit and dishonesty”, Independent, 23 April 2009<br />

9


of <strong>tax</strong>payers affected; but it will hardly solve <strong>the</strong> problem. That will require broader, more<br />

painful measures in <strong>the</strong> medium term.” 38<br />

In an editorial <strong>the</strong> Times argued, “<strong>the</strong> Chancellor has not simply increased <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> to 50<br />

per cent, he also moved <strong>the</strong> starting date to within this <strong>Parliament</strong> in direct breach of a<br />

central manifesto pledge. As <strong>the</strong> birth of this pledge [in <strong>the</strong> 1997 general election] was<br />

symbolic, so is its death.” The paper was also doubtful as to <strong>the</strong> amounts of money that<br />

would be raised by <strong>the</strong> new <strong>rate</strong>:<br />

The decision to raise <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> to 50 per cent will punish some bankers, but<br />

will simply send o<strong>the</strong>rs scurrying to Geneva. The vast majority of <strong>the</strong> 350,000 people<br />

earning more than £150,000 will, of course, stay in <strong>the</strong> UK. They will not complain.<br />

They will call <strong>the</strong>ir accountants. A higher <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> is likely to gene<strong>rate</strong> much less<br />

revenue than <strong>the</strong> Treasury hopes, and much more avoidance. But Mr Darling is also<br />

guilty of <strong>tax</strong> avoidance. His Budget sidestepped <strong>the</strong> central issue of <strong>the</strong> public finances:<br />

it answered <strong>the</strong> problem of future spending with a commitment to future borrowing but<br />

no clear or plausible route to reducing debt. 39<br />

The leader in <strong>the</strong> Financial Times went fur<strong>the</strong>r to argued that “<strong>the</strong> plans to raise <strong>tax</strong>es on <strong>the</strong><br />

rich … are not about raising money”:<br />

The most striking measures [in <strong>the</strong> Budget speech] were undoubtedly <strong>the</strong> plans to<br />

raise <strong>tax</strong>es on <strong>the</strong> rich. … There is force in <strong>the</strong> argument that a government needing to<br />

raise revenue should focus on those who have more money ra<strong>the</strong>r than those who<br />

have less. A fair <strong>tax</strong> system must be progressive. But <strong>the</strong> more a country raises money<br />

from a small number of rich people, <strong>the</strong> fewer of <strong>the</strong>m it will find it has. Raising serious<br />

revenue requires a broad <strong>tax</strong> base, not an assault on a small minority of high earners.<br />

But <strong>the</strong>se rises are not about raising money: indeed, <strong>the</strong> Institute for Fiscal Studies has<br />

argued that <strong>the</strong> current top <strong>rate</strong> of 40 per cent was <strong>the</strong> revenue-maximising <strong>rate</strong>, and<br />

that <strong>the</strong> planned increase would cost <strong>the</strong> exchequer ra<strong>the</strong>r than help plug <strong>the</strong> hole.<br />

These <strong>tax</strong> plans exemplify <strong>the</strong> relentlessly tactical nature of yesterday's Budget - a<br />

mixture of populism and procrastination. Perhaps it is too much to hope for a st<strong>rate</strong>gic<br />

approach in <strong>the</strong> run-up to an election. But <strong>the</strong> Budget has at least set out <strong>the</strong> clear<br />

division between <strong>the</strong> main political parties over how to share <strong>the</strong> pain of getting public<br />

finances into shape. Now we need a truthful debate about what this should entail,<br />

including what activities <strong>the</strong> state undertakes that it should cease to perform. Credible<br />

politicians must engage with this argument. 40<br />

Writing in <strong>the</strong> Times, Anatole Kaletsky argued that <strong>the</strong> new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was “a pointless and<br />

unexpected gamble”:<br />

The announcement of any significant <strong>tax</strong> increase, at a time when <strong>the</strong> Chancellor was<br />

trying to restore business confidence and boost housing and consumption, went<br />

completely against <strong>the</strong> logic of efforts of <strong>the</strong> Government's faith in fiscal stimulus … [In<br />

addition] by accelerating his <strong>tax</strong> plans, <strong>the</strong> Chancellor has probably delayed and<br />

weakened <strong>the</strong> recovery that <strong>the</strong> Treasury is expecting this year ... Third, and most<br />

alarmingly, Mr Darling's <strong>tax</strong> increase has kicked <strong>the</strong> most cyclically important part of<br />

<strong>the</strong> British economy when it is already down … in today's more cost-conscious<br />

38<br />

39<br />

40<br />

“Leader: Despe<strong>rate</strong> Measures”, Economist, 25 April 2009<br />

“Leader: The avoidance Budget”, Times, 23 April 2009<br />

“Leader: Too frail and vague to shore up credibility”, Financial Times, 23 April 2009<br />

10


environment, banks and multinational companies will be sorely tempted by <strong>the</strong> neardoubling<br />

of net pay that <strong>the</strong>y can achieve for <strong>the</strong>ir employees simply by moving out of<br />

Britain before Mr Darling's new <strong>tax</strong>es and national insurance charges are imposed. <strong>41</strong><br />

Never<strong>the</strong>less, opinion polls carried out after <strong>the</strong> Budget found widespread public support for<br />

<strong>the</strong> new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. The Times reported on a poll by Populus which showed 57% of<br />

respondents welcoming <strong>the</strong> change, with 22% against. This contrasted with reactions to <strong>the</strong><br />

rises in fuel duty <strong>rate</strong>s: with just 20% in favour and 68% opposed. 42 Commenting on <strong>the</strong><br />

apparent mismatch between <strong>the</strong> responses of editorial writers and newspaper readers to <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Guardian suggested that this was “partly a case of self-interest … [but also] a<br />

more general failure on <strong>the</strong> part of <strong>the</strong> elite to grasp how exceptionally rich someone on<br />

£150,000 … really is.” 43<br />

Provision to allow <strong>the</strong> new <strong>additional</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> to be applied from April 2010 was included in<br />

<strong>the</strong> Finance Act 2009 (section 6). <strong>Income</strong> <strong>tax</strong> is an annual <strong>tax</strong> re-imposed each year by<br />

<strong>Parliament</strong> (even if <strong>the</strong> proposed <strong>rate</strong>s are <strong>the</strong> same as for <strong>the</strong> previous year), so that <strong>the</strong><br />

Government anticipated that <strong>the</strong> Finance Bill <strong>the</strong> following year would introduce <strong>the</strong> charge to<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> for 2010/11, and set <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, along with <strong>the</strong> basic and higher <strong>rate</strong>s of<br />

<strong>tax</strong>. At <strong>the</strong> conclusion of <strong>the</strong> Committee debate, Sir Nicholas Winterton, Chairman of <strong>the</strong><br />

Committee, explained that it was appropriate for <strong>the</strong> Bill to include this clause, though it did<br />

not provide exactly when <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> would come in: “The clause, in my estimation and<br />

on <strong>the</strong> advice that I have taken, is <strong>the</strong> setting of a top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong>, without specifying that top<br />

<strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong>, which could come in future legislation.” 44<br />

The <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was mentioned a few times by Members during <strong>the</strong> second reading of <strong>the</strong> Bill<br />

on 6 May 2009. Justifying <strong>the</strong> change <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Chief Secretary to <strong>the</strong> Treasury, Yvette<br />

Cooper, said, “we think that it is fairest for those on <strong>the</strong> highest incomes to contribute more<br />

because over <strong>the</strong> past 10 years <strong>the</strong>ir incomes have increased by an average of £5,000 a<br />

year, compared with £600 a year for <strong>the</strong> average <strong>tax</strong>payer.” 45 Robert Syms took issue with<br />

<strong>the</strong> amount of money that this <strong>additional</strong> contribution might raise:<br />

If we are honest, <strong>the</strong> only way to raise an awful lot of <strong>tax</strong> revenue is to raise <strong>tax</strong> on<br />

ordinary working people, not on a particular section of people. High <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s might<br />

make a debating point, but <strong>the</strong> reality of <strong>the</strong> Government’s policy of raising <strong>the</strong> higher<br />

<strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s, restricting allowances and restricting what people can do with pensions is<br />

that people will look for o<strong>the</strong>rs ways to recompense <strong>the</strong>mselves. They might forgo<br />

salary in <strong>the</strong> short term or look for o<strong>the</strong>r ways, such as capitalising <strong>the</strong>ir salary. 46<br />

The <strong>the</strong>n shadow Chief Secretary, Philip Hammond, criticised <strong>the</strong> change as a “political<br />

gesture” which would create “a yet more complex system of <strong>tax</strong>ation.” Mr Hammond was<br />

also concerned about <strong>the</strong> associated increase in <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on trusts:<br />

<strong>41</strong><br />

42<br />

43<br />

44<br />

45<br />

46<br />

“Bad economics, timing and politics: but a good impression of Mr Bean”, Times, 23 April 2009<br />

“Tax rise at <strong>the</strong> top wins applause as Brown denies <strong>the</strong> death of new Labour”, Times, 24 April 2009<br />

“Middle England welcomes <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> for high earners”, Guardian, 25 April 2009<br />

Public Bill Committee (Finance Bill) 21 May 2009 c95. The Act also contained provision for <strong>the</strong> tapering of <strong>the</strong><br />

personal allowance from individuals with incomes over £100,000 (section 4).<br />

HC Deb 6 May 2009 c184<br />

HC Deb 6 May 2009 c236. The Financial Times soon reported this trend in <strong>tax</strong> planning (”Investors seek to<br />

shift away from <strong>tax</strong> traps”, 2/3 May 2009).<br />

11


In aligning <strong>the</strong> trust <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> with <strong>the</strong> new, higher <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, HMRC made <strong>the</strong><br />

assumption that all beneficiaries of trusts are people who are likely to be subject to <strong>the</strong><br />

top <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong>. That is simply not <strong>the</strong> case. Although it may have been a<br />

broadly reasonable assumption when <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> was 40 per cent., it is an<br />

unreasonable assumption when <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> affects only those people with an<br />

income of more than £150,000. There will be many beneficiaries of trusts with incomes<br />

far below <strong>the</strong> £150,000 threshold whose income will now be subject to <strong>tax</strong> at <strong>the</strong> 50 per<br />

cent. <strong>rate</strong>. That undermines still fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> legitimate use of trusts, and should be<br />

carefully considered. 47<br />

Winding up <strong>the</strong> debate <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Financial Secretary, Stephen Timms, responded to this<br />

point:<br />

Rates were aligned in 2004 to prevent avoidance of <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> by routeing income<br />

through a trust. The trust <strong>rate</strong> will be increased in line with <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong>, so we are<br />

not opening up opportunity for trusts to be used for avoidance. Those for whom <strong>the</strong><br />

lower <strong>rate</strong> is appropriate can reclaim <strong>tax</strong>; many do so already. In <strong>the</strong> case of selfassessment,<br />

that will happen automatically. If, as was suggested, <strong>the</strong> trust is for a<br />

vulnerable beneficiary or a bereaved child, for example, an election can be made<br />

under <strong>the</strong> vulnerable beneficiary legislation, which has a special <strong>tax</strong> regime. 48<br />

Similar points were raised when <strong>the</strong>se provisions were debated at <strong>the</strong> Committee stage of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Bill. The Financial Secretary explained why <strong>the</strong> Government had changed its proposals<br />

since <strong>the</strong> PBR in November 2008:<br />

As you will recall, it was announced in <strong>the</strong> pre-Budget report in November that we<br />

would be introducing a 45 per cent. <strong>rate</strong> in April 2011. However, <strong>the</strong> global downturn<br />

has been worse than predicted and, as a result, more consolidation is required. That is<br />

why <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> has been brought forward and raised by five percentage points<br />

to 50 per cent … We have thought very carefully about how <strong>the</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r money required<br />

for fiscal consolidation should be raised. We are clear that it is right to require those<br />

who benefited most in <strong>the</strong> last decade and who are in <strong>the</strong> best position to pay to<br />

contribute more. That is <strong>the</strong> basis for <strong>the</strong> clause. 49<br />

Speaking for <strong>the</strong> Conservatives, Greg Hands suggested that “<strong>the</strong> new <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>’s<br />

implementation is largely <strong>the</strong> result of political posturing.” He raised concerns that <strong>the</strong><br />

change of policy between <strong>the</strong> 2008 PBR and <strong>the</strong> 2009 Budget had undermined <strong>the</strong> UK’s<br />

reputation as having a ‘predictable and stable’ <strong>tax</strong> code, and questioned whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> new<br />

<strong>rate</strong> would raise as much as predicted, especially as it would increase <strong>the</strong> differential<br />

between <strong>the</strong> highest <strong>rate</strong> on income <strong>tax</strong>, and <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of capital gains <strong>tax</strong>. 50<br />

Jeremy Browne, speaking for <strong>the</strong> Liberal Democrats, took issue with what he termed <strong>the</strong><br />

‘ethical’ case for <strong>the</strong> 50 <strong>rate</strong>, that, “it was only right that <strong>the</strong> people who benefited from<br />

economic growth should pay more now that <strong>the</strong> economy is shrinking”:<br />

First, those who are earning <strong>the</strong> most money already contribute a much bigger<br />

percentage of <strong>the</strong> total national income <strong>tax</strong> take than <strong>the</strong>ir numbers would o<strong>the</strong>rwise<br />

47<br />

48<br />

49<br />

50<br />

HC Deb 6 May 2009 cc197-8. The Chartered Institute of Taxation also argued <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong> trust <strong>rate</strong> is<br />

“punitive, forcing distribution of income” (CIOT Budget 2009, 1 May 2009 p1).<br />

HC Deb 6 May 2009 cc310-11<br />

Public Bill Committee (Finance Bill) 19 May 2009 c45, c48<br />

PBC 19 May 2009 c49, c61, c67<br />

12


indicate. One could argue that <strong>the</strong>y should contribute more or that <strong>the</strong>y should<br />

contribute less, but it is misleading to suggest that <strong>the</strong> top 1 or 2 per cent. of earners<br />

are not contributing in a substantial and meaningful way to <strong>the</strong> public finances; <strong>the</strong>y<br />

most certainly are. Secondly, one should not necessarily assume that people who will<br />

be earning in excess of £150,000 from next year onwards benefited during <strong>the</strong> period<br />

of economic growth. 51<br />

4 Debate on <strong>the</strong> potential yield of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

At <strong>the</strong>ir briefing after <strong>the</strong> 2009 Budget, Robert Chote, <strong>the</strong>n director of <strong>the</strong> IFS, put <strong>the</strong><br />

changes to income <strong>tax</strong> on <strong>the</strong> wealthy into some context:<br />

Much attention has focussed on <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> increases on <strong>the</strong> rich, which <strong>the</strong><br />

Treasury hopes will raise £7 billion a year. Even if this estimate is correct, <strong>the</strong> gain will<br />

partly be offset by losses of VAT and o<strong>the</strong>r indirect <strong>tax</strong> revenues buried in o<strong>the</strong>r Budget<br />

forecasting changes. We should also bear in mind that increases in fuel duty and<br />

National Insurance will raise a roughly similar amount – and from a much broader<br />

range of families. And all <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> increases announced to date will in total raise only<br />

about 10% of <strong>the</strong> money <strong>the</strong> Treasury is looking for by 2017–18. So <strong>the</strong> main burden of<br />

<strong>the</strong> looming tightening – at least over <strong>the</strong> next few years – is likely to fall on <strong>the</strong> users<br />

of public services. 52<br />

In a presentation on <strong>the</strong> Budget changes to direct <strong>tax</strong>es and benefits, Stuart Adam of <strong>the</strong> IFS<br />

noted that <strong>the</strong>re was “huge uncertainty about how much people will reduce <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong>able<br />

income in response”, observing that <strong>the</strong>y might “work less, retire earlier, emig<strong>rate</strong>, contribute<br />

more to [a] pension or charity, convert income to capital gains, incorpo<strong>rate</strong>, [or] invest in <strong>tax</strong><br />

avoidance.” Moreover <strong>the</strong> Treasury’s estimate that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> would raise £2.4bn ignored<br />

any effect on consumer spending, and <strong>the</strong> consequent fall in indirect <strong>tax</strong> revenues. 53<br />

In its submission to <strong>the</strong> Treasury Committee on <strong>the</strong> Budget, <strong>the</strong> Institute of Chartered<br />

Accountants noted <strong>the</strong> IFS’ work on this issue, saying “given <strong>the</strong> weight of evidence that<br />

such <strong>rate</strong>s may not be effective in raising revenue, we [are of] <strong>the</strong> view that a detailed<br />

economic analysis of <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> proposed 50% <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> needs to be made, before any<br />

such policy is implemented.” 54 For its part, <strong>the</strong> Committee heard evidence from <strong>the</strong> Treasury<br />

that it anticipated that individuals would be relatively successful in reducing <strong>the</strong>ir liability to<br />

<strong>the</strong> new <strong>rate</strong>; Mike Williams (Director, Personal Tax and Welfare Reform) explained <strong>the</strong><br />

department’s modelling of <strong>the</strong>se behavioural changes as follows:<br />

The modelling exercise assumes that of <strong>the</strong> total <strong>the</strong>oretical yield that you would get<br />

from <strong>the</strong> extra 10 percentage points from 2011-12 onwards that we would get about<br />

31% of that ... What it is about is of <strong>the</strong> total extra <strong>the</strong>oretically obtainable <strong>the</strong> best<br />

estimate made, taking into account behaviour, is that we will get just over 30% of that<br />

… If you take <strong>the</strong> costing in two parts, first, you look at how many people <strong>the</strong>re will be<br />

with incomes above, say, £150,000 in 2011-12 and apply <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong>, where you<br />

51<br />

52<br />

53<br />

54<br />

PBC 19 May 2009 c72<br />

Reactions to Budget 2009 : Opening remarks - Robert Chote, IFS 23 April 2009. The Budget projections for<br />

2009-10 from VAT and corporation <strong>tax</strong> were £8.8bn & £7.7bn lower than those made in <strong>the</strong> 2008 PBR (HC<br />

407 March 2009 p231).<br />

IFS Budget 2009 : Direct <strong>tax</strong>es and benefits - Stuart Adam, IFS 23 April 2009. On this <strong>the</strong>me see, “Ten ways<br />

to survive high-<strong>tax</strong> Britain”, Sunday Times, 26 April 2009.<br />

ICAEW Tax Faculty, 2009 Budget Submission TAXREP 14/09, March 2009 p2<br />

13


were previously applying <strong>the</strong> 40% <strong>rate</strong>, and that gives you one figure, <strong>the</strong> maximum<br />

<strong>the</strong>oretically obtainable figure. What is scored and what we think is <strong>the</strong> best estimate<br />

after behaviour from 2011-12 onwards is 31%, but just to clarify yet fur<strong>the</strong>r, because of<br />

course <strong>the</strong>re is interaction with <strong>the</strong> pensions <strong>tax</strong> measure 55 , if you <strong>the</strong>n take into<br />

account <strong>the</strong> pensions <strong>tax</strong> measure that in itself acts to reduce <strong>the</strong> behavioural effect<br />

from <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong> and if you take <strong>the</strong> two toge<strong>the</strong>r, which you can choose to or you<br />

can deal with <strong>the</strong>m sepa<strong>rate</strong>ly, that takes <strong>the</strong> behavioural effect down so <strong>the</strong> yield goes<br />

up to about 38%. 56<br />

When <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Chancellor, Alistair Darling, appeared before <strong>the</strong> Committee, he was asked if<br />

this apparently high-level of avoidance might not undermine public support for <strong>the</strong> measure;<br />

he responded by saying:<br />

Tax-planning has been with us, presumably, since <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> 19th Century<br />

when, you will remember, income <strong>tax</strong> was introduced on a temporary basis during <strong>the</strong><br />

Napoleonic Wars and, I dare say, ye olde <strong>tax</strong> planners have been doing a roaring trade<br />

ever since. It is perfectly legitimate for people to <strong>tax</strong>-plan. They are only obliged to<br />

render unto Caesar what is due to Caesar and that has always been a feature of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

case. What I tried to do here though, I am raising revenue both in indirect <strong>tax</strong>es and<br />

from next year from those earning over £100,000 in direct <strong>tax</strong>es, and of course I will<br />

always be vigilant about loopholes and indeed we announced various measures in <strong>the</strong><br />

Budget <strong>the</strong>re. I think <strong>the</strong> answer to your question is that to dig up <strong>the</strong> entire system at<br />

<strong>the</strong> present time would have been, I think, difficult to justify. 57<br />

At an earlier point in <strong>the</strong>se exchanges, Mr Darling said:<br />

If you see <strong>the</strong> yield that comes in from those measures, and this one, I think, is about<br />

£2.4 billion when it is <strong>the</strong>re totally, it is quite a substantial sum of revenue. All I would<br />

say to people who tell me <strong>the</strong>y do not want me to do it is, “Okay, so what else are you<br />

suggesting? Where else would you go?” There is no getting away from <strong>the</strong> fact that we<br />

do need to take steps to deal with <strong>the</strong> result of <strong>the</strong> fact of our corpo<strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong> revenues,<br />

which could well come back in years to come, which, for as long as banks do not make<br />

any money, <strong>the</strong>y will not be paying any <strong>tax</strong>es. 58<br />

Mr Darling was also asked why he had chosen to set <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> at <strong>50p</strong> on incomes<br />

over £150,000:<br />

You ask me why I chose <strong>the</strong> level of £150,000 and that was simply my judgment. I had<br />

to balance reluctantly, if you like, because, having spent <strong>the</strong> best part of 10 years in a<br />

government that had essentially two <strong>rate</strong>s of <strong>tax</strong>, I think it is important that we are<br />

competitive, but in <strong>the</strong> present circumstances, and o<strong>the</strong>r governments are going to be<br />

confronted with this, we need to take action to support our economy and also to live<br />

within our means, and I thought this was a fair thing to do. 59<br />

For its part <strong>the</strong> Committee raised serious concerns about <strong>the</strong> way in which <strong>the</strong> new structure<br />

had been designed, and <strong>the</strong> amounts of money that it could reasonably be expected to raise:<br />

55<br />

56<br />

57<br />

58<br />

59<br />

[As mentioned above, Budget 2009 also announced <strong>the</strong> tapering of <strong>tax</strong> relief on pension contributions for<br />

individuals with incomes above £150,000.]<br />

Eighth report: Budget 2009, 6 May 2009 HC 438-II 2008-09 Q219 Ev30<br />

HC 438-II 2008-09 Q343 Ev45<br />

HC 438-II 2008-09 Q338 Ev 44<br />

HC 438-II 2008-09 Q336 Ev 43-4<br />

14


We … recommend that <strong>the</strong> Treasury, in <strong>the</strong> 2011 Pre-Budget Report, should report on<br />

<strong>the</strong> revenue raised, both nominally and as a percentage of <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical maximum<br />

revenue, by <strong>the</strong> new top <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong>. We also recommend that <strong>the</strong> Treasury<br />

assess at that time <strong>the</strong> yield obtained from <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> against its disadvantages. If<br />

<strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> were to be continued it would be appropriate to consider what fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

reforms would be needed to prevent fur<strong>the</strong>r leakage of potential revenue from this<br />

measure. The Treasury should indicate if it would revise <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in <strong>the</strong> event that <strong>the</strong><br />

estimated revenue yield fell well below <strong>the</strong>ir forecasts. 60<br />

The Government published its response to <strong>the</strong> report in July 2009, and made <strong>the</strong> following<br />

remarks in answer to this point:<br />

The costings of <strong>the</strong> 50 per cent income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> are based on careful assessment of<br />

<strong>the</strong> impact, including any behavioural responses, on all relevant receipts and revenues.<br />

As <strong>the</strong> Government has made clear to <strong>the</strong> Treasury Select Committee, <strong>the</strong><br />

Government has accounted for a proportion of high income individuals using various<br />

methods to reduce <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong> and NICs liabilities. The Government believes that this<br />

represents a fair estimate of <strong>the</strong> impact of this measure. The Government is committed<br />

to ensuring that everyone continues to pay <strong>the</strong>ir fair share whatever <strong>the</strong>ir income. As<br />

with all <strong>tax</strong>es, <strong>the</strong> Government will keep <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> under review. HM Revenue<br />

and Customs update each year income <strong>tax</strong> information contained on <strong>the</strong>ir website. 61<br />

In November 2010 <strong>the</strong> IFS published <strong>the</strong> draft conclusions to a major review of <strong>the</strong> UK <strong>tax</strong><br />

system, which had been chaired by Sir James Mirrlees. In <strong>the</strong>ir discussion of <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong>ation of<br />

earnings, <strong>the</strong> authors reviewed <strong>the</strong> work done by IFS researchers on <strong>the</strong> potential yield of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, and <strong>the</strong> debate over a revenue-maximising top <strong>rate</strong> – but went on to argue that <strong>the</strong><br />

significance of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> lay less in <strong>the</strong> “paltry sum it might raise (or cost)”, but more in<br />

what it represented about wider attitudes about wealth and inequality:<br />

Tax rises impose losses on those affected even if <strong>the</strong>y raise no revenue: those who do<br />

pay more lose out financially, while those who change <strong>the</strong>ir behaviour to avoid <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong><br />

are still somewhat worse off—o<strong>the</strong>rwise <strong>the</strong>y would have changed <strong>the</strong>ir behaviour<br />

even in <strong>the</strong> absence of <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong>. If we put any value at all on <strong>the</strong> extra satisfaction <strong>the</strong><br />

rich derive from becoming even richer, <strong>the</strong> revenue-maximising <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> will be too<br />

high. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, if we find extreme affluence so abhorrent that it is worth<br />

making <strong>the</strong> rich worse off even if it raises no money—indeed, worth making <strong>the</strong> rest of<br />

<strong>the</strong> population slightly worse off in order to make <strong>the</strong> rich significantly worse off—<strong>the</strong>n<br />

<strong>the</strong> revenue-maximising <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> will be too low.<br />

Such considerations are particularly pertinent because, around <strong>the</strong> revenuemaximising<br />

<strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, even sizeable changes in <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s would have little impact on<br />

revenue, yet still impose significant losses on those affected. Society’s attitude to those<br />

losses is <strong>the</strong>refore as important as <strong>the</strong> precise revenue effect. The significance of <strong>the</strong><br />

50% income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> is less <strong>the</strong> paltry sum it might raise (or cost) than <strong>the</strong> substantial<br />

hit on high earners it represents. 62<br />

A longer extract from <strong>the</strong> final report, which was published in September 2011, is reproduced<br />

at <strong>the</strong> end of this note.<br />

60<br />

61<br />

62<br />

HC 438-I 2008-09 para 100<br />

Fifth special report, 10 July 2009 HC 890 2008-09 p12<br />

“Chapter 4: Reforming <strong>the</strong> Taxation of Earnings in <strong>the</strong> UK” in, Tax By Design: <strong>the</strong> Mirrlees Review (Preliminary<br />

version), November 2010 pp 35-7<br />

15


5 The 2010 Budget<br />

Following <strong>the</strong> 2009 Budget, and debates over <strong>the</strong> new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, <strong>the</strong>re were a series of press<br />

reports of companies paying employees ahead of time to miss <strong>the</strong> new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, 63 of <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong><br />

authorities signalling <strong>the</strong>ir determination to crack down on any new avoidance schemes, 64<br />

and accountants suggesting that many entrepreneurs and financiers were considering<br />

leaving <strong>the</strong> UK. 65 On this last point, it is notable that a survey of <strong>the</strong> banking sector after <strong>the</strong><br />

new <strong>rate</strong> came in found little evidence of any exodus of senior executives to low <strong>tax</strong> havens<br />

in Geneva or Zurich, for <strong>the</strong> simple reason that typically <strong>the</strong>y could still earn twice as much in<br />

London after <strong>tax</strong>, such was <strong>the</strong> relative size of London’s financial market. 66<br />

That said, over <strong>the</strong> next months <strong>the</strong> focus of public attention moved on to wider concerns: <strong>the</strong><br />

severity of <strong>the</strong> economic recession, <strong>the</strong> continuing decline in <strong>the</strong> public finances, and <strong>the</strong> fact<br />

that whichever government took power after <strong>the</strong> 2010 General Election, it would have to<br />

consider much larger <strong>tax</strong> increases or major cuts in public spending, or, most likely, both.<br />

In <strong>the</strong>ir Green Budget, published in February 2010, <strong>the</strong> Institute for Fiscal Studies looked at a<br />

wide range of possible <strong>tax</strong> increases and benefit cuts that might be implemented to reduce<br />

<strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> public deficit. <strong>Income</strong> <strong>tax</strong> is <strong>the</strong> largest <strong>tax</strong> in terms of <strong>the</strong> money it raises for<br />

government; taken with <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r two big <strong>tax</strong>es - VAT and National Insurance – <strong>the</strong>se three<br />

raise about 60% of all Exchequer revenues. Indeed, changes to <strong>the</strong>se <strong>tax</strong>es would raise<br />

very large sums: 1% of national income (£15.4 billion in 2011/12 terms) could be raised by a<br />

3 percentage point rise in <strong>the</strong> basic and higher <strong>rate</strong>s of <strong>tax</strong> (to 23% and 43%). In <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

discussion of this, and o<strong>the</strong>r possible revenue-raising changes to income <strong>tax</strong>, <strong>the</strong> authors<br />

explained, “we do not consider increasing <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> ‘<strong>additional</strong>’ <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, which will apply above<br />

£150,000 from April 2010, as previous research has shown that, at best, very little <strong>additional</strong><br />

revenue could be expected to be raised from doing so.” 67<br />

In his 2010 Budget speech <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Chancellor, Alistair Darling, simply confirmed <strong>the</strong><br />

introduction of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, along with a number of o<strong>the</strong>r pre-announced <strong>tax</strong> increases<br />

aimed at those on higher incomes:<br />

First, on <strong>tax</strong>es, I have already made difficult decisions, and I have been guided by our<br />

values of fairness and <strong>the</strong> need not to undermine <strong>the</strong> recovery. The one penny<br />

increase in <strong>the</strong> main <strong>rate</strong> of national insurance contributions will not affect anyone<br />

earning under £20,000 a year; nor will it come into effect until April next year, by which<br />

time I expect that <strong>the</strong> recovery will be stronger and more secure. The 50 per cent. <strong>rate</strong><br />

of income <strong>tax</strong> will come in next month, but it affects only those with earnings over<br />

£150,000 a year-<strong>the</strong> top 1 per cent. of earners. For people with incomes over £100,000<br />

a year-<strong>the</strong> top 2 per cent.-we will gradually remove <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong>ir personal<br />

allowances. Tax relief on pensions will be restricted from next year, but again only for<br />

those with incomes above £130,000 a year.<br />

63<br />

64<br />

65<br />

66<br />

67<br />

For example, “Taxman loses as dividends spring forward”, Financial Times, 6/7 March 2010<br />

“Revenue warns high earners of <strong>tax</strong> avoidance crackdown”, Financial Times, 8/9 October 2009<br />

For example, two Financial Times reports: “Accountants warn of 50% <strong>tax</strong> exodus”, 19/20 September 2009 &<br />

“Tax rise may spark entrepreneur exodus”, 5/6 December<br />

“Banking exodus fears on 50% <strong>tax</strong> overdone”, Financial Times, 17 May 2010<br />

The IFS Green Budget, February 2010 p135, p138<br />

16


Among all <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> rises since <strong>the</strong> beginning of this global crisis, 60 per cent. of <strong>the</strong>m<br />

will be paid for by <strong>the</strong> top 5 per cent. of earners. We have not raised <strong>the</strong>se <strong>tax</strong>es out of<br />

dogma or ideology; we are determined to ensure that our overall <strong>tax</strong> regime remains<br />

competitive. But I believe that those who have benefited <strong>the</strong> most from <strong>the</strong> strong<br />

growth in incomes in <strong>the</strong> past years should now pay <strong>the</strong>ir fair share of <strong>tax</strong>. I have no<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r announcements on VAT, on income <strong>tax</strong> or on national insurance <strong>rate</strong>s. 68<br />

Provision for <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was included in <strong>the</strong> Finance Bill, published at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> Budget<br />

debates on 30 March. 69 The Bill was relatively shorter than usual, to take account of <strong>the</strong> fact<br />

that <strong>the</strong>re would be a limited amount of <strong>Parliament</strong>ary time available before <strong>the</strong> General<br />

Election. As it transpired, <strong>the</strong> date of <strong>the</strong> Election was announced just a few days later, with<br />

<strong>the</strong> Dissolution of <strong>the</strong> House set for 12 April. This left 2 days of <strong>Parliament</strong>ary time for <strong>the</strong><br />

conclusion of all legislative business, and <strong>the</strong> Finance Bill was debated, and approved, in its<br />

entirety in three hours on 7 April – with little reference being made to <strong>the</strong> new income <strong>tax</strong><br />

structure. 70<br />

The three major parties made no mention of any fur<strong>the</strong>r changes to <strong>the</strong> new higher <strong>rate</strong><br />

during <strong>the</strong> Election campaign. 71 For <strong>the</strong>ir part, <strong>the</strong> Conservatives stated that <strong>the</strong>y did not<br />

“regard <strong>the</strong> new <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> as a permanent feature of <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> system” but that <strong>the</strong>y would<br />

not “abolish it for <strong>the</strong> rich while at <strong>the</strong> same time asking many of our public sector workers to<br />

accept a pay freeze.” 72 In addition, <strong>the</strong> party made no mention of increasing <strong>the</strong> £150,000<br />

threshold in line with inflation or earnings.<br />

By way of comparison a written answer in <strong>the</strong> Lords in January 2010 provides some figures<br />

for <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong>s of <strong>tax</strong> in <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r G7 countries: 73<br />

Asked by Baroness Valentine: To ask Her Majesty's Government how <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of<br />

United Kingdom income <strong>tax</strong> compared with o<strong>the</strong>r G7 countries in (a) 2000, and (b)<br />

2010; and what plans <strong>the</strong>y have to address that aspect of <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom's<br />

competitiveness.[HL5928]<br />

The Commercial Secretary to <strong>the</strong> Treasury (Lord Sassoon): Top marginal <strong>tax</strong> and<br />

social security <strong>rate</strong>s are not necessarily representative of <strong>the</strong> total burden of <strong>tax</strong>ation<br />

on earnings, which depend on <strong>the</strong> income thresholds at which <strong>the</strong>se <strong>rate</strong>s apply as<br />

well as <strong>the</strong> burden of employer social security contributions.<br />

Tax wedge data offer a more comprehensive measure of <strong>the</strong> total burden of <strong>tax</strong>ation<br />

on earnings, as <strong>the</strong>y account for both of <strong>the</strong>se considerations. G7 <strong>tax</strong> wedge data for<br />

high income individuals are not immediately available for 2000 and 2010. However, a<br />

limited range of data is published by <strong>the</strong> OECD in its annual Taxing Wages document<br />

(latest edition published May 2010-http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/19/13/45118806.pdf).<br />

As of April 2010, <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> in <strong>the</strong> UK is 50 per cent. This <strong>rate</strong> was<br />

introduced by <strong>the</strong> previous Government, and will remain in place for <strong>the</strong> time being.<br />

However, we believe that high marginal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s are not good for <strong>the</strong> UK and we will<br />

68<br />

69<br />

70<br />

71<br />

72<br />

73<br />

HC Deb 24 March 2010 cc255-6<br />

It is now set out in s1 of <strong>the</strong> Finance Act 2010.<br />

HC Deb 7 April 2010 cc 1058-1105. In <strong>the</strong> very short Committee stage debates, <strong>the</strong> House considered 3<br />

clauses, but not <strong>the</strong> clause setting <strong>the</strong> charge and <strong>rate</strong>s of income <strong>tax</strong> for <strong>the</strong> coming <strong>tax</strong> year.<br />

A summary of <strong>the</strong> three parties’ <strong>tax</strong> policies was provided in, Taxes and benefits: <strong>the</strong> parties’ plans: Institute<br />

for Fiscal Studies Election Briefing Note BN100, 27 April 2010<br />

Conservative Party, Where we stand: Economy, 2010<br />

HL Deb 31 January 2011 cc240-1WA<br />

17


continue to look at <strong>the</strong> yields from different <strong>tax</strong>es, including <strong>the</strong> 50 per cent <strong>rate</strong>, to<br />

ensure that <strong>the</strong>y remain an efficient and effective way of raising revenue.<br />

Top Statutory <strong>Income</strong> Employee social security contributions<br />

Tax <strong>rate</strong> (as % of at top of income <strong>tax</strong> threshold<br />

gross income) (as % of gross income) Combined<br />

2000 2010 2000 2010 2000 2010<br />

Canada 46.3% 45.6% 0% 0% 46.3% 45.6%<br />

France 58.3% 47.8% 11% 11% 69.6% 59.0%<br />

Germany 53.8% 47.5% 0% 0% 53.8% 47.5%<br />

Italy 45.9% 43.8% 9.2% 10.5% 55.1% 54.3%<br />

Japan 50% 50% 0.4% 0.4% 50.4% 50.4%<br />

UK 40% 50% 0% 1% 40.0% 51.0%<br />

USA 45.6% <strong>41</strong>% 1.5% 1.5% 47.1% 42.5%<br />

*Notes:<br />

Canada<br />

(1) Top Federal <strong>rate</strong> is 29%. Average of top provincial <strong>rate</strong>s (including surcharges) is 16.6%<br />

(2010). Highest combined <strong>rate</strong> applies in Quebec (54%).<br />

(2) Social Security contribution ceiling is CAN$45,000 (approx £23,000)<br />

France<br />

(1) Top statutory <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> is 40% (rising to <strong>41</strong>% in 2011). Two Social contributions also<br />

apply to gross income, CRDS and CSG and are included in <strong>the</strong> calculation above.<br />

(2) Social Security contributions are deductible for personal income <strong>tax</strong>.<br />

Germany<br />

Social security contribution ceiling is €64,000. Combined with high contribution <strong>rate</strong>s means that<br />

individuals fur<strong>the</strong>r down <strong>the</strong> income scale can face higher marginal <strong>rate</strong>s than top earners. For<br />

example an individual earning €<strong>41</strong>,000 (approx. £35,000) and facing full social security<br />

contribution <strong>rate</strong>s would face a marginal combined <strong>rate</strong> of 56%.<br />

Italy<br />

Top statutory <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> is 43% in 2010. Regional up to a maximum <strong>rate</strong> of 1.4% also<br />

applies.<br />

Japan<br />

Top statutory <strong>rate</strong> of state income <strong>tax</strong> is 40%. 10% flat <strong>rate</strong> local <strong>tax</strong> also applies.<br />

USA<br />

Since 2001 top federal income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> is 35% but this is due to expire in 2013 and return to<br />

2000 level of 39.6%. Average of state top income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s = approx 6%.<br />

6 The Coalition Government’s approach<br />

On 20 May 2010 <strong>the</strong> new Conservative-Liberal Democrat Coalition Government published<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir coalition agreement: this made no mention of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, though it indicated that it<br />

would make a number of <strong>tax</strong> changes in its first Budget:<br />

The Government believes that <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> system needs to be reformed to make it more<br />

competitive, simpler, greener and fairer. We need to take action to ensure that <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong><br />

framework better reflects <strong>the</strong> values of this Government.<br />

18


• We will increase <strong>the</strong> personal allowance for income <strong>tax</strong> to help lower and<br />

middle income earners. We will announce in <strong>the</strong> first Budget a substantial<br />

increase in <strong>the</strong> personal allowance from April 2011, with <strong>the</strong> benefits focused<br />

on those with lower and middle incomes. This will be funded with <strong>the</strong> money<br />

that would have been used to pay for <strong>the</strong> increase in employee National<br />

Insurance thresholds proposed by <strong>the</strong> Conservative Party, as well as revenues<br />

from increases in Capital Gains Tax <strong>rate</strong>s for non-business assets as<br />

described below. The increase in employer National Insurance thresholds<br />

proposed by <strong>the</strong> Conservatives will go ahead in order to stop <strong>the</strong> planned jobs<br />

<strong>tax</strong>.<br />

• We will fur<strong>the</strong>r increase <strong>the</strong> personal allowance to £10,000, making real terms<br />

steps each year towards meeting this as a longer-term policy objective. We will<br />

prioritise this over o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>tax</strong> cuts, including cuts to Inheritance Tax. 74<br />

In his Budget statement on 22 June 2010, <strong>the</strong> Chancellor, George Osborne announced that<br />

<strong>the</strong> personal allowance would rise by £1,000 to £7,475 from April 2011. The threshold at<br />

which <strong>tax</strong>payers become liable to <strong>the</strong> 40% higher <strong>rate</strong> will be cut at this time, to prevent<br />

higher <strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payers benefitting from this change. Mr Osborne also confirmed an increase<br />

in <strong>the</strong> threshold for employers paying National Insurance contributions on <strong>the</strong>ir employee’s<br />

earnings from April 2011, as well as a rise in <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of capital gains <strong>tax</strong> for higher <strong>rate</strong><br />

<strong>tax</strong>payers. 75 However, <strong>the</strong> most significant <strong>tax</strong> change which <strong>the</strong> Chancellor announced, in<br />

monetary terms, was a rise in <strong>the</strong> standard <strong>rate</strong> of VAT from 17.5% to 20% from 4 January<br />

2011. It was estimated that <strong>the</strong> new standard <strong>rate</strong> will raise £12.1bn in 2011/12: by<br />

comparison <strong>the</strong> £1,000 rise in <strong>the</strong> personal allowance will cost £3.49bn in 2011/12. 76 On <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>additional</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Budget report simply stated: “<strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> took effect<br />

from April 2010 and will remain in place for <strong>the</strong> time being.” 77<br />

Unsurprisingly comment on <strong>the</strong> new Government’s first Budget was dominated by <strong>the</strong> rise in<br />

<strong>the</strong> standard <strong>rate</strong> of VAT, though in a review of its approach <strong>the</strong> OECD suggested <strong>the</strong> EU<br />

should consider reducing <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of personal income <strong>tax</strong>: <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of Personal<br />

<strong>Income</strong> Tax [PIT] “is substantially above <strong>the</strong> OECD average and likely to adversely affect<br />

work incentives and entrepreneurship, particularly of high skilled workers. Consideration<br />

should be given to reducing <strong>the</strong> top PIT <strong>rate</strong> to close to 40 per cent.” 78 In <strong>the</strong> weeks before<br />

<strong>the</strong> 2011 Budget, <strong>the</strong>re was more speculation that <strong>the</strong> Government might review <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong>, given its concerns to ensure that <strong>the</strong> UK remains internationally competitive, and<br />

updated predictions of <strong>the</strong> large share of income <strong>tax</strong> receipts paid by those with <strong>the</strong> very<br />

highest incomes. 79 (HMRC now estimate that in 2010/11 <strong>tax</strong>payers on <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

were liable to pay £34.5bn, compared with total income <strong>tax</strong> liabilities of £152bn. 80 )<br />

In an opinion piece critical of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, Jo Johnson MP noted that three quarters of those<br />

expected to pay it would be in sectors o<strong>the</strong>r than banking – “many of <strong>the</strong>se will be precisely<br />

<strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs <strong>the</strong> UK must attract to stimulate job creation and quicken its sluggish<br />

recovery from recession”:<br />

74<br />

75<br />

76<br />

77<br />

78<br />

79<br />

80<br />

HM Government, The Coalition: our programme for government, 20 May 2010 p30<br />

HC Deb 22 June 2010 c179<br />

Budget 2010 HC 61 June 2010 p40<br />

HC 61 June 2010 p32<br />

OECD, United Kingdom - Policies for a Sustainable Recovery, July 2010 p25<br />

“Top 1% of earners set to pay quarter of all income <strong>tax</strong>”, Financial Times, 12/13 February 2011<br />

National Statistics: <strong>Income</strong> <strong>tax</strong> liabilities, by income source and <strong>tax</strong> band (Table 2.6), January 2013<br />

19


Those who seemingly despise bankers, a distressingly large proportion of <strong>the</strong><br />

electo<strong>rate</strong>, hail [<strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>] as a progressive <strong>tax</strong> on City "fat cats". It is rapidly<br />

becoming clear, however, that it is a ra<strong>the</strong>r crude instrument for <strong>the</strong> collective<br />

punishment of this banker class, somewhat like <strong>the</strong> EU fishing quotas that encourage<br />

trawlers to catch and discard more fish than <strong>the</strong>y ever take to shore … In a letter to <strong>the</strong><br />

parliamentary public accounts committee, [Sir Nicholas Macpherson, <strong>the</strong> permanent<br />

secretary to <strong>the</strong> Treasury] revealed that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> is paid by three times more<br />

innocent bystanders than bankers. 81 Out of 275,000 affected, only 63,000 - 23 per cent<br />

- work in "financial intermediation". Many of <strong>the</strong>se collateral victims, of course, will be<br />

precisely <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurs <strong>the</strong> UK must attract to stimulate job creation and quicken<br />

its sluggish recovery from recession.<br />

The result is that, just as countries need to compete for highly skilled labour as never<br />

before, <strong>the</strong> UK is seen as a high-<strong>tax</strong> economy … It is also not clear that <strong>the</strong> 50 per cent<br />

<strong>rate</strong> will raise <strong>the</strong> revenue <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Labour government forecast in <strong>the</strong> March 2010<br />

Budget. Back <strong>the</strong>n, <strong>the</strong> estimated revenue was £1.3bn in 2010-11, £3.1bn in 2011-12<br />

and £2.7bn in 2012-13. The first year of its operation <strong>the</strong>refore comes to an end this<br />

month, which means that <strong>the</strong> Treasury will in due course begin to have a sense of<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> is actually making a meaningful contribution to <strong>the</strong> job of deficit<br />

reduction …<br />

But even if <strong>the</strong> Treasury receives <strong>the</strong> revenues forecast in last year's Budget, <strong>the</strong>y will<br />

be unlikely to compensate for <strong>the</strong> damage to <strong>the</strong> UK's international competitiveness.<br />

This leaves <strong>the</strong> government facing a dilemma. On <strong>the</strong> one hand, <strong>the</strong>re are huge<br />

political difficulties in even signalling an intention eventually to cut <strong>tax</strong>es for <strong>the</strong> well-off<br />

(in line with reductions in all o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>rate</strong>s of <strong>tax</strong>ation and only once <strong>the</strong> public sector pay<br />

freeze is lifted) at a time of hardship for <strong>the</strong> poor and difficulties for many lower- and<br />

middle-income families. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, in a global economy, no prudent<br />

government will want to lumber itself with Harold Wilson-esque <strong>rate</strong>s of personal<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> for a second longer than necessary. 82<br />

In his Budget speech on 23 March 2011, Mr Osborne confirmed that <strong>the</strong>re would be no<br />

change in <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s of income <strong>tax</strong> for <strong>the</strong> coming year, though he suggested that <strong>the</strong> case for<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> should be re-examined once <strong>the</strong>re was comprehensive data on <strong>the</strong> amounts of<br />

money it had actually raised for <strong>the</strong> Exchequer in its first year:<br />

In an age when business and capital and people can increasingly move anywhere,<br />

high <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s can do real damage. That is true for high corpo<strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s, and it is<br />

true for high personal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s too. They crush enterprise, undermine aspiration and<br />

often undermine <strong>tax</strong> revenues as people avoid <strong>the</strong>m. I am clear that <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

would do lasting damage to our economy if it were to become permanent. That is why I<br />

regard it as a temporary measure, just as my Labour predecessor, <strong>the</strong> right hon.<br />

Member for Edinburgh South West (Mr Darling), did when he introduced it. I have said<br />

before that now would not be <strong>the</strong> right time to remove it when we are asking o<strong>the</strong>rs in<br />

our society on much lower incomes to make sacrifices, for we are all in this toge<strong>the</strong>r,<br />

but I think it is sensible to see how much revenue it actually raises. I have asked Her<br />

Majesty's Revenue and Customs- [ Interruption. ] I have asked HMRC to find out <strong>the</strong><br />

truth when <strong>the</strong> self-assessment forms start coming in. 83<br />

81<br />

82<br />

83<br />

Public Accounts Committee, Banking support: written evidence from HM Treasury 16 March 2011 HC 973<br />

2010/11<br />

“Why a high-<strong>tax</strong> London is a disaster for Britain”, Financial Times, 17 March 2011<br />

HC Deb 23 March 2011 c957<br />

20


Provision to set <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s of income <strong>tax</strong> for <strong>the</strong> 2011/12 <strong>tax</strong> year was included in <strong>the</strong> Finance<br />

Act 2011 (specifically section 1 of <strong>the</strong> Act). When this provision was debated at <strong>the</strong><br />

Committee stage of <strong>the</strong> Finance Bill, David Hanson MP, speaking for <strong>the</strong> Opposition, moved<br />

an amendment to require <strong>the</strong> Government to publish “terms of reference, a timetable and<br />

updates” on <strong>the</strong> department’s review of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, akin to a formal consultation: “it is<br />

inclement on [<strong>the</strong> Minister] to say to <strong>the</strong> House, ‘This is <strong>the</strong> time scale. This is who will<br />

undertake it. This is when it will report. This is how you put evidence into it. This is when we<br />

will make a decision for a future Budget on whe<strong>the</strong>r that <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> stays or goes’.” 84 In<br />

response <strong>the</strong> Exchequer Secretary, David Gauke, explained why HMRC had been given this<br />

task, but rejected <strong>the</strong> case for taking this approach:<br />

HMRC is undertaking <strong>the</strong> review because it is important that all <strong>the</strong> information<br />

available on <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong> is considered, and only HMRC can analyse individual selfassessment<br />

returns, because <strong>the</strong>y contain confidential <strong>tax</strong>payer information … In<br />

looking at <strong>the</strong> issue, HMRC’s main challenge will be to isolate <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> from o<strong>the</strong>r factors. In light of that, it will conclude its analysis as soon as<br />

it is practical to do so.<br />

Its findings will <strong>the</strong>n be used to inform <strong>the</strong> Government’s wider thinking on <strong>tax</strong>ation<br />

policy, with any announcements made by <strong>the</strong> Chancellor as part of <strong>the</strong> annual Budget<br />

process in <strong>the</strong> usual manner. Of course, <strong>the</strong> Government keep all <strong>tax</strong>es under review<br />

and reserve <strong>the</strong> right to announce changes at <strong>the</strong> appropriate time. Indeed, <strong>tax</strong><br />

changes are generally made at Budgets. Given that, <strong>the</strong>re is no reason to accept <strong>the</strong><br />

amendment.<br />

The Minister went on to explain that as self-assessment returns for <strong>the</strong> 2010/11 year would<br />

be filed by <strong>the</strong> end of January 2012, HMRC will be reviewing this data “in early 2012.” 85 The<br />

amendment was put to a vote, and negatived by 16 votes to 14.<br />

The issue was debated a second time at <strong>the</strong> report stage of <strong>the</strong> Bill, when <strong>the</strong> Opposition put<br />

down an amendment to require <strong>the</strong> Office for Budget Responsibility to produce a report on<br />

<strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. Moving <strong>the</strong> amendment David Hanson MP stated, “we want<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r explanation of <strong>the</strong> methodology that <strong>the</strong>y will use to consider <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> for<br />

future Budgets, and I think that <strong>the</strong> best organisation to do that is <strong>the</strong> Office for Budget<br />

Responsibility.” 86 Opposing <strong>the</strong> amendment <strong>the</strong> Exchequer Secretary argued that HMRC<br />

were best placed to review <strong>the</strong> data on <strong>the</strong> yield from <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, and criticised <strong>the</strong> way in<br />

which <strong>the</strong> Labour Government had introduced it:<br />

As I explained during <strong>the</strong> extensive debate on this clause in Committee … HMRC will<br />

consider all <strong>the</strong> available evidence on <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, including data<br />

from <strong>the</strong> 2010-11 self-assessment returns, which will become available next year. Data<br />

from <strong>tax</strong> returns are clearly essential in any assessment of <strong>the</strong> revenue raised, but of<br />

course <strong>the</strong>y contain confidential <strong>tax</strong>payer information and are best reviewed by HMRC.<br />

It already has <strong>the</strong> expertise in monitoring and evaluating <strong>tax</strong> measures and is<br />

resourced to do so in future. The Office for Budget Responsibility has a different remit<br />

in producing independent economic and fiscal forecasts, judging policy against <strong>the</strong><br />

fiscal mandate and analysing <strong>the</strong> sustainability of <strong>the</strong> public finances …<br />

84<br />

85<br />

86<br />

Public Bill Committee (Finance Bill) 10 May 2011 c10<br />

op.cit. c22, c29. This point was also made in answer to PQs on this issue (eg, HC Deb 19 May 2011 c325W).<br />

HC Deb 4 July 2011 c1324<br />

21


As <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was introduced by <strong>the</strong> previous Government, I can perfectly<br />

understand why <strong>the</strong> right hon. Member for Delyn [Mr Hanson] is so interested in<br />

establishing whe<strong>the</strong>r it was a successful policy, but when he talks about public scrutiny<br />

of Budget measures I must ask him what public scrutiny was <strong>the</strong>re when <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

was introduced? To what extent was <strong>the</strong> analysis published <strong>the</strong>n, and to what extent<br />

was it published when <strong>the</strong> 10p <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> was doubled? What information was<br />

put into <strong>the</strong> public domain at that point? As a Government, we have done much more<br />

on putting information into <strong>the</strong> public domain by publishing our analysis.<br />

Announcements in this area will be made by <strong>the</strong> Chancellor at <strong>the</strong> appropriate time. It<br />

is peculiar, however, to hear <strong>the</strong> Opposition proposing more evidence-based policy<br />

making only to reject <strong>the</strong> notion, it seems to me, that this Government should consider<br />

<strong>the</strong> evidence before making any fur<strong>the</strong>r commitments. 87<br />

The amendment was put to <strong>the</strong> vote and negatived by 298 votes to 229.<br />

Running up to <strong>the</strong> 2012 Budget <strong>the</strong>re was a great deal of debate over <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, much of it<br />

in response to a letter published in September 2011 in <strong>the</strong> Financial Times, signed by<br />

DeAnne Julius, Chairman of Chatham House, and nineteen o<strong>the</strong>r leading economists:<br />

Sir, We welcome <strong>the</strong> government putting <strong>the</strong> promotion of growth at <strong>the</strong> top of its<br />

agenda given <strong>the</strong> fragile state of <strong>the</strong> UK economy . O<strong>the</strong>r major economies have got<br />

back to pre-recession output levels; <strong>the</strong> UK has not.<br />

In this context, we are concerned that Britain's <strong>50p</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> is doing lasting<br />

damage to <strong>the</strong> UK economy. It gives <strong>the</strong> UK one of <strong>the</strong> highest personal <strong>tax</strong> regimes in<br />

<strong>the</strong> industrialised world, making it less competitive internationally and making us less<br />

attractive as a destination for both foreign investment and talented workers.<br />

The UK has already slipped from second to fourth place as a destination for inward<br />

investment. It punishes wealth creation by imposing on entrepreneurs and business<br />

people a marginal <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in excess of 50 per cent once national insurance<br />

contributions are added in. This is particularly damaging when <strong>the</strong> UK needs to create<br />

new businesses in new industries and promote growth by small companies, which can<br />

grow fast. It applies to just 1 per cent of <strong>tax</strong>payers, who already pay 24 per cent of all<br />

income <strong>tax</strong>es.<br />

If a small portion of <strong>the</strong>se highly mobile workers move elsewhere because of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> <strong>the</strong>n it is clearly a self-defeating way for <strong>the</strong> Treasury to try to raise money, and a<br />

reduction in <strong>tax</strong> avoidance would be more effective. It is often portrayed as a justified<br />

<strong>tax</strong> on <strong>the</strong> rich but <strong>the</strong> economic damage it causes means that it is against <strong>the</strong> interests<br />

even of ordinary workers who don't pay it.<br />

We call on <strong>the</strong> government to drop <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> at <strong>the</strong> earliest opportunity as part of a<br />

package of measures to stimulate growth. Only by returning to an internationally<br />

competitive <strong>tax</strong> regime will Britain enjoy long-term sustainable economic growth. 88<br />

Following this <strong>the</strong> paper published a series of letters from both supporters and critics of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, 89 and <strong>the</strong> debate continued elsewhere, as commentators speculated as to what its<br />

future might be. 90 As <strong>the</strong> IFS noted at <strong>the</strong> time, “rarely has <strong>the</strong>re been such a wide debate<br />

87<br />

88<br />

89<br />

90<br />

HC Deb 4 July 2011 cc1332-3<br />

“Letters: Government must abolish <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> to grow UK economy”, Financial Times, 7 September 2011 –<br />

see also, “Debate goes on in wake of 20 economists' letter to <strong>the</strong> FT : Q&A”, 8 September 2011.<br />

“Letters : Costs and <strong>tax</strong>es mean <strong>the</strong> take is not worth <strong>the</strong> effort”, 9 September 2011; “Letters : UK <strong>tax</strong> debate<br />

needs to consider capital gains”, 12 September 2011; “Letters : Top-<strong>rate</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> will not lead ntrepreneurs<br />

to move abroad”, 13 September 2011<br />

For example, “Tax ‘staying for now’…”, Times, 8 September 2011; “Should high earners pay less <strong>tax</strong>?”,<br />

Sunday Times, 11 September 2011; “Head to head: Should <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> go?”, Guardian, 8 September 2011;<br />

“Diving into <strong>the</strong> rich pool”, Economist, 24 September 2011<br />

22


about an issue of <strong>tax</strong> policy based on so little empirical evidence.” This observation was<br />

made in <strong>the</strong> IFS’ 2012 Green Budget published in February 2012 in which it examined <strong>the</strong><br />

issue in some depth. 91 The analysis drew on much of <strong>the</strong> research that has already been<br />

mentioned in this note, and it is not proposed to do it full justice here. That said, <strong>the</strong> authors<br />

made some striking points about <strong>the</strong> limitations to any data <strong>the</strong> Chancellor would have, to<br />

inform any decision about <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>:<br />

The first evidence on <strong>the</strong> revenue raised by <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> will be contained in <strong>tax</strong><br />

returns for <strong>the</strong> 2010–11 <strong>tax</strong> year, which need to be submitted to HMRC by 31 January<br />

2012 … This gives less than two months for [HMRC to review <strong>the</strong>se figures] … even<br />

assuming <strong>the</strong> data will be fully processed and available to researchers at <strong>the</strong> beginning<br />

of February. But <strong>tax</strong> records for just one year after <strong>the</strong> introduction of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> are<br />

unlikely to provide a robust estimate of how much revenue <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> will raise, for<br />

several reasons.<br />

First, <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was announced over a year before its implementation … this<br />

gave high-income individuals <strong>the</strong> incentive to bring forward income to 2009–10 to avoid<br />

paying <strong>the</strong> increased <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. So <strong>tax</strong> revenues in <strong>the</strong> first year of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong>’s<br />

operation are likely to be particularly low and those in <strong>the</strong> prior year particularly high.<br />

Second, one year after <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong>’s implementation might be too soon for some individuals<br />

to respond fully to <strong>the</strong> new <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. In particular, those who decided to leave <strong>the</strong> UK<br />

following <strong>the</strong> announcement of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> might not have had enough time to<br />

arrange this, such that <strong>the</strong> revenue implications might be higher going forward.<br />

Third, because <strong>the</strong> Chancellor has said that he views <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> as a temporary<br />

measure, individuals are likely to behave differently from if <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> change were<br />

believed to be permanent. On <strong>the</strong> one hand, individuals are more likely to engage in<br />

responses that involve shifting income to a future date when an increase is temporary.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, individuals are less likely to engage in responses that have a large<br />

fixed cost, such as moving away from <strong>the</strong> UK. A sepa<strong>rate</strong> issue is that <strong>the</strong> ongoing<br />

economic crisis will likely make it difficult for HMRC staff to distinguish between <strong>the</strong><br />

impact of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on <strong>tax</strong> revenues and <strong>the</strong> impact of o<strong>the</strong>r economic forces on <strong>the</strong><br />

incomes of <strong>the</strong> richest 1%. For example, many of <strong>the</strong> richest 1% are employed in <strong>the</strong><br />

financial services industry and are likely to have seen <strong>the</strong>ir incomes fall significantly<br />

during <strong>the</strong> early part of <strong>the</strong> recent recession before rebounding strongly in 2010–11.<br />

As <strong>the</strong>y concluded, “Budget 2012 is almost certainly too soon to be making decisions on <strong>the</strong><br />

future of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> if <strong>the</strong>y are to be informed by reliable, robust empirical evidence.”<br />

Moving on from this, and echoing <strong>the</strong>mes to <strong>the</strong> Mirrlees review, <strong>the</strong> authors argued that <strong>the</strong><br />

focus <strong>the</strong>re has been on <strong>the</strong> money that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> may raise is “an an unduly narrow<br />

approach to <strong>tax</strong> policy”:<br />

Even if it raised money, it may not be <strong>the</strong> least socially harmful way of raising <strong>the</strong> same<br />

amount of revenue, even from <strong>the</strong> same or similar people. Since most of <strong>the</strong><br />

behavioural response to high <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s appears to take <strong>the</strong> form of <strong>tax</strong> avoidance, an<br />

obvious way to increase revenue might be to reduce <strong>the</strong> opportunities that exist for <strong>tax</strong><br />

avoidance – for example, by aligning income and CGT <strong>rate</strong>s, <strong>the</strong>reby negating any<br />

advantage to taking remuneration as capital gains ra<strong>the</strong>r than income. But any reforms<br />

such as this would need to be carefully thought through and implemented as part of a<br />

wider st<strong>rate</strong>gy for <strong>tax</strong> policy. Effective <strong>tax</strong> policy requires a clear st<strong>rate</strong>gy, an<br />

understanding of how <strong>the</strong> system as a whole works toge<strong>the</strong>r, and a consistent and<br />

91<br />

“Chapter 9: <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>: what is known and what will be known?”, in, The IFS 2012 Green Budget,<br />

February 2012 pp 180-196.<br />

23


concerted approach to reform. Decisions about <strong>the</strong> abolition or retention of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong>, and about any measures to increase revenues from <strong>the</strong> richest individuals, should<br />

be considered as part of a clear forward st<strong>rate</strong>gy. We can ill-afford poorly-thought-out,<br />

short-term and un-joined-up <strong>tax</strong> policymaking. 92<br />

7 The 2012 Budget : cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> to 45p<br />

The Chancellor George Osborne delivered his third Budget on 21 March 2012. In his speech<br />

Mr Osborne referred to his earlier concerns over <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, and explained that <strong>the</strong><br />

department had found evidence that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> had caused “massive distortions”, in<br />

particular with <strong>tax</strong>payers, forewarned about <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> taking effect, shifting income into <strong>the</strong><br />

2009/10 year to avoid paying it. Moreover HMRC had revised its analysis of this behavioural<br />

impact, and this suggested that cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> to 45p would cost relatively little – an<br />

assessment that <strong>the</strong> Office of Budget Responsibility found to be reasonable. This contrasted<br />

with <strong>the</strong> amounts of money <strong>the</strong> Government expected to raise from <strong>tax</strong>payers on <strong>the</strong> highest<br />

incomes from a number of o<strong>the</strong>r Budget measures. As a consequence he proposed setting<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> at 45p from April 2013.<br />

An extract from <strong>the</strong> Budget speech is reproduced below:<br />

[The <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>] is widely acknowledged by business organisations and international<br />

observers as harming <strong>the</strong> British economy. Like <strong>the</strong> previous Chancellor who<br />

introduced it, I have always said that it was temporary. But I also said, three years ago,<br />

that I would not be prepared to reduce it while we were asking <strong>the</strong> whole public sector<br />

to accept a pay freeze, and I will stick to those pledges.<br />

A <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, with all <strong>the</strong> damage it does to Britain’s competitiveness, can only be<br />

justified if it raises significant sums of money. In last year’s Budget, I asked Her<br />

Majesty’s Revenue and Customs to look at <strong>the</strong> evidence, and especially to look at <strong>the</strong><br />

self-assessment <strong>tax</strong> receipts that have come in since this January. I am publishing its<br />

report today. What it reveals is that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> has caused massive distortions.<br />

HMRC finds that an astonishing £16 billion of income was delibe<strong>rate</strong>ly shifted into <strong>the</strong><br />

previous <strong>tax</strong> year, at a cost to <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payer of £1 billion—something that <strong>the</strong> previous<br />

Government’s figures made no allowance for whatsoever. Self-assessment receipts<br />

this year are below forecast by some £3.6 billion, while o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>tax</strong> receipts have held up.<br />

The increase from 40p to <strong>50p</strong> raised just a third of <strong>the</strong> £3 billion that we were told it<br />

would raise.<br />

Of course, <strong>the</strong> previous Government initially proposed a <strong>rate</strong> of 45p and <strong>the</strong>n increased<br />

that to <strong>50p</strong>. Let me tell <strong>the</strong> House what HMRC says about <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>50p</strong><br />

and 45p. … The direct cost is only £100 million a year. Indeed, HMRC calculates that<br />

<strong>the</strong> loss of o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>tax</strong> revenues may even cancel that out. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, it raises at<br />

most a fraction of what we were told, and may raise nothing at all. So from April next<br />

year, <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> will be 45p. … No Chancellor can justify a <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> that<br />

damages our economy and raises next to nothing—it is as simple as that...<br />

These days <strong>the</strong> direct costing that <strong>the</strong> Treasury applies to every Budget measure is<br />

independently assessed and certified by <strong>the</strong> OBR. Unlike <strong>the</strong> previous Government, it<br />

92<br />

The IFS 2012 Green Budget, February 2012 p195, p196<br />

24


also assesses <strong>the</strong> cash flow consequences of forestalling. When it comes to <strong>the</strong> £100<br />

million direct permanent costs of this measure, <strong>the</strong> OBR says this: “we believe that this<br />

is a reasonable and central estimate”. It also assesses as reasonable <strong>the</strong> estimate that<br />

<strong>the</strong> new <strong>tax</strong>es that I have introduced on <strong>the</strong> rich today directly raise five times that<br />

amount. That is half a billion pounds that we can now use to help people on lower and<br />

middle incomes keep more of <strong>the</strong>ir earnings. 93<br />

The ‘new <strong>tax</strong>es’ to which <strong>the</strong> Chancellor referred were a new 7% <strong>rate</strong> of stamp duty on<br />

properties worth £2m or more, provisions to prevent individuals avoiding <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> by buying<br />

property through a company, and a cap on certain income <strong>tax</strong> reliefs. 94<br />

The department’s assessment of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> are set out in a detailed report; 95 it would be<br />

infeasible to précis this work here, though <strong>the</strong>re are some points which are worth underlining.<br />

First, <strong>the</strong> report anticipated about 300,000 people would be liable to pay <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> –<br />

around 1% of <strong>tax</strong>payers. The share of total income <strong>tax</strong> revenues paid by this top one<br />

percentile of <strong>tax</strong>payers has been steadily growing over <strong>the</strong> past twenty years: from about<br />

15% in 1990/91 to an estimated 27% in 2011/12. Almost half of <strong>the</strong>se individuals work in<br />

business services or financial intermediation. 96<br />

Second, as discussed in <strong>the</strong> earlier sections of this note, <strong>the</strong> critical tool used to estimate <strong>the</strong><br />

amounts of money higher <strong>rate</strong>s can raise is <strong>the</strong> ‘<strong>tax</strong>able income elasticity’ (TIE) - <strong>the</strong><br />

percentage change in total <strong>tax</strong>able incomes in response to a one per cent change in <strong>the</strong> netof-<strong>tax</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> (<strong>the</strong> proportion of each <strong>additional</strong> pound earned received by <strong>the</strong> individual after<br />

<strong>tax</strong>, also known as <strong>the</strong> marginal retention <strong>rate</strong>). In <strong>the</strong> March 2010 Budget <strong>the</strong> Treasury had<br />

used a TIE of 0.35 – suggesting that behavioural responses to <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> would reduce its<br />

yield by about two-thirds, reducing <strong>the</strong> extra liabilities of <strong>the</strong> affected individuals by about<br />

£4.5 billion, to £2.4 billion in 2010/11. This estimate was on a liabilities basis, as opposed to<br />

a National accounts basis: 97<br />

• The “liabilities basis‟ shows <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> measure on <strong>tax</strong> liabilities in any<br />

particular <strong>tax</strong> year, as opposed to a “cash basis‟ which shows <strong>the</strong> impact on <strong>tax</strong><br />

payments (<strong>the</strong>re is often a lag between a <strong>tax</strong> liability arising and <strong>the</strong> date at which it<br />

must be paid to HMRC).<br />

• The National Accounts basis is a mixture of liabilities and cash, depending on <strong>the</strong> type<br />

of <strong>tax</strong>. In particular, PAYE receipts are recorded on a liabilities basis, while Self<br />

Assessment receipts, which are partly due in <strong>the</strong> year after <strong>the</strong> liability arises, are<br />

scored on a cash basis. This basis is used in <strong>the</strong> published Budget measures table.<br />

So, while <strong>the</strong> yield for <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was estimated to be £2.4bn for 2010/11 and 2011/12 on a<br />

liabilities basis, <strong>the</strong> Budget report, using a National Accounts basis, gave estimates of £1.3bn<br />

and £3.1bn respectively. 98<br />

93<br />

94<br />

95<br />

96<br />

97<br />

98<br />

HC Deb 21 March 2012 cc805-6<br />

The Budget report estimated that toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>se changes would raise £565m by 2015/16: HC 1853, March<br />

2012 (Table 2.1 – items 4,5 & 6) p50.<br />

HMRC, The Exchequer effect of <strong>the</strong> 50 per cent <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong>, March 2012<br />

op.cit. pp 12-13. This was <strong>the</strong> projected <strong>tax</strong> base at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> March 2010 Budget. HMRC now estimate<br />

that 236,000 people paid <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in 2010/11 (National Statistics : Table 2.1, January 2013).<br />

op.cit. p16<br />

Budget 2010 HC 451 March 2010 p140 (Table A11 – item l)<br />

25


Work by researchers at <strong>the</strong> IFS prepared <strong>the</strong> Mirrlees Review had suggested a TIE of 0.46, 99<br />

and academic studies using US data “have shown that TIEs tend to be higher for those with<br />

higher incomes as <strong>the</strong>y engage more in <strong>tax</strong> planning and are more mobile.” Moreover, <strong>the</strong><br />

data <strong>the</strong> department had received on payments made under self-assessment for 2010/11<br />

suggested a much greater behavioural response than initially expected. Overall, incomes<br />

among those with incomes above £150k increased 14% in 2009/10 but fell 25% in 2010/11.<br />

This trend was strongest for dividend income – which grew 78% among this group in 2009/10<br />

and <strong>the</strong>n fell 73% in 2010/11. 100 To ascertain <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> <strong>the</strong> department had<br />

to make an estimate of <strong>the</strong> counterfactual to <strong>the</strong>se figures – how incomes would have grown<br />

if <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s had been unchanged. Then, in looking at how receipts would be affected by<br />

future <strong>tax</strong> changes, it was necessary to make allowance for <strong>the</strong> fact that forestalling – simply<br />

moving income from one <strong>tax</strong> year to ano<strong>the</strong>r – would have a short-run impact on receipts,<br />

compared with o<strong>the</strong>r behaviours (such as emigration).<br />

All told <strong>the</strong> department estimated that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> had raised about £1 billion at most:<br />

behavioural responses had decreased <strong>the</strong> yield from <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> by at least 83% - an<br />

implied TIE of 0.48. As <strong>the</strong>y concluded, “<strong>the</strong>se results are more in line with those that would<br />

be produced using <strong>the</strong> behavioural response estimates contained in academic literature. This<br />

conclusion is also consistent with <strong>the</strong> £3.6 billion shortfall in Self Assessment <strong>tax</strong> revenues<br />

observed in January and February 2012 (<strong>the</strong> months in which balancing payments relating to<br />

2010-11 liabilities are received).” 101<br />

The last step was to use this estimate of <strong>tax</strong>payer responses to estimate how much <strong>the</strong><br />

Exchequer would lose from cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. In general studies of TIEs have not taken a<br />

consistent approach on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>tax</strong>payers would react differently to <strong>rate</strong> reductions to <strong>rate</strong><br />

increases – though <strong>the</strong>re are some reasons to doubt that <strong>the</strong>ir behaviour would be<br />

symmetric: “Up-front investment in <strong>tax</strong> planning could lead to some “stickiness” when <strong>the</strong><br />

income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> is reduced – for example avoidance scheme would still be more <strong>tax</strong> efficient<br />

and may have been setup to ope<strong>rate</strong> for a number of years. Taxpayers who shifted to<br />

evasion behaviours may still under report <strong>the</strong>ir income. Where individuals have mig<strong>rate</strong>d it is<br />

possible that <strong>the</strong>y may not moved back to <strong>the</strong> UK.” 102<br />

The department elected to use a slightly lower TIE of 0.45 – and based on this, estimated<br />

that setting <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> at 45p from 2013/14 would only lower total yields by about<br />

£100m a year. 103 At this time many commentators noted this was a critical assumption –<br />

including <strong>the</strong> BBC’s economics editor Stephanie Flanders:<br />

There is clearly room to wonder whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> behavioural change will be symmetrical. If<br />

you have spent a lot of money setting up a company, for example, to avoid <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong>, it's not obvious you will break that up now <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> is 45p. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, it's<br />

plausible that some o<strong>the</strong>r money will come back into <strong>the</strong> system. It really is too soon to<br />

say. What is certain is that millions of basic and higher <strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payers people will pay<br />

less <strong>tax</strong> next year as a result of this budget. And that <strong>the</strong> UK is less than half way<br />

through an unprecedented seven-year programme of <strong>tax</strong> rises and spending cuts that -<br />

99<br />

This work is discussed in section 1 of this note.<br />

100 HMRC, March 2012 p20, pp28-9<br />

101 op.cit. p45<br />

102 op.cit. p23<br />

103 op.cit. p51<br />

26


<strong>the</strong> chancellor suggested on Wednesday - could involve a fur<strong>the</strong>r £10bn in welfare cuts<br />

from 2014-15. 104<br />

In a piece before <strong>the</strong> Budget, in <strong>the</strong> light of considerable speculation that <strong>the</strong> Chancellor<br />

would cut <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, 105 Ms Flanders noted that any claim that <strong>the</strong> rich would be paying<br />

more, say from cracking down on <strong>tax</strong> avoidance would be “ra<strong>the</strong>r tricky to prove … it’s not<br />

that forecasts are dishonest. It’s just that, to put it bluntly, <strong>the</strong> money all looks <strong>the</strong> same<br />

when it comes in. The wealthy entrepreneur doesn’t usually attach a note saying that he<br />

usually manages not to pay much <strong>tax</strong> but this year he’d been forced to cough up.” 106<br />

In <strong>the</strong>ir commentary on this assessment <strong>the</strong> Office for Budget Responsibility agreed that <strong>the</strong><br />

TIE of 0.45 was a “reasonable and central estimate”, but went on to underline <strong>the</strong><br />

considerable uncertainties to <strong>the</strong>se forecasts:<br />

Taken at face value <strong>the</strong> HMRC study might suggest an even higher TIE, but this would<br />

risk placing put too much weight on a single year’s outturn evidence – especially given<br />

<strong>the</strong> complications from disentangling <strong>the</strong> forestalling effect. There is also reason to<br />

believe that <strong>the</strong> behavioural response to <strong>the</strong> cut in <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> may be smaller than to<br />

<strong>the</strong> increase, because of <strong>the</strong> costs involved in swiftly reversing expensive decisions on<br />

retirement, migration, <strong>tax</strong> planning and evasion. But it is very important to emphasise<br />

<strong>the</strong> significant uncertainties around all such estimates. 107<br />

Robert Chote, head of <strong>the</strong> OBR, was asked about <strong>the</strong> department’s assessment when he<br />

gave evidence to <strong>the</strong> Treasury Committee after <strong>the</strong> Budget; he suggested that this was a<br />

particularly difficult exercise because it was necessary to disentangle <strong>the</strong> impact of<br />

forestalling from o<strong>the</strong>r behavioural responses. Mr Chote was also pressed by Teresa Pearce<br />

MP as to why HMRC had thought future forestalling would be equivalent to £6.5bn, a much<br />

lower figure than <strong>the</strong> £16bn estimates of forestalling that was thought to have happened<br />

before <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> took effect: anticipated<br />

Q85 Teresa Pearce: … Looking at some of <strong>the</strong> figures, it is estimated that £16 billion<br />

of income was shifted <strong>the</strong>n, but what is obviously going to happen is that people are<br />

going to shift again, but <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r way. Yet you have estimated only £6.25 billion for<br />

that, which seems quite low to me …<br />

Robert Chote: One issue is obviously that <strong>the</strong> differential in <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s is half of<br />

what it previously was.<br />

Q86 Teresa Pearce: Half of quite a lot is still quite a lot.<br />

Robert Chote: It is quite a lot. The o<strong>the</strong>r point is that in <strong>the</strong> case of avoiding <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong>, <strong>the</strong>re were several years in <strong>the</strong> future that you could shift <strong>the</strong> income out of into<br />

<strong>the</strong> year prior to <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> change happening. In this case, you have only this year to<br />

shift it out of into <strong>the</strong> future year in order to take advantage of <strong>the</strong> lower <strong>rate</strong>, so <strong>the</strong>re is<br />

a smaller pool of time period to shift your income out of.<br />

Q87 Teresa Pearce: Even so, in your estimate, it looks as though in 2012–13 <strong>the</strong>re<br />

will be a £3 billion drop in revenue, because of people shifting <strong>the</strong> income.<br />

Robert Chote: That is right. Roughly, if you have £6 billion, that is <strong>the</strong> impact.<br />

104 “Budget 2012: A big debate about small numbers (cont'd)”, BBC News online, 21 March 2012<br />

105 “Top <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> to fall to 45p after bitter budget talks finally end”, Sunday Times, 18 March 2012<br />

106 “Budget 2012: A big debate about small numbers”, BBC News online, 20 March 2012<br />

107 Cm 8303, March 2012 p109<br />

27


Q88 Teresa Pearce: That is a big number, and <strong>the</strong> assumption is that it will come in<br />

<strong>the</strong> later year.<br />

Robert Chote: As I say, you are looking <strong>the</strong>re specifically at <strong>the</strong> forestalling effect—<strong>the</strong><br />

simple time shifting. There is <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> sepa<strong>rate</strong> issue of what has been <strong>the</strong> underlying<br />

behavioural response that you might expect to persist as a result of labour supply<br />

responses or of permanent changes to <strong>tax</strong> planning behaviour and so on. It is a heroic<br />

exercise to try to disentangle those two components and to quantify <strong>the</strong>m. 108<br />

In his commentary on <strong>the</strong> Budget <strong>the</strong> director of <strong>the</strong> IFS, Paul Johnson, contrasted <strong>the</strong><br />

uncertainties to this estimate with <strong>the</strong> fact that, without any change, cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

to 45p would cost £3bn a year:<br />

HMRC’s analysis suggests that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> only raised around £1 billion in 2010-11, a<br />

lot less than <strong>the</strong> £2.6 billion previously forecast by <strong>the</strong> Treasury and – prior to<br />

yesterday –assumed in <strong>the</strong> OBR’s forecasts. As <strong>the</strong> HMRC put it, “it is difficult to<br />

construct a plausible outcome consistent with a yield estimate as high as those original<br />

forecasts”. And some of <strong>the</strong> data <strong>the</strong>y base this on are certainly dramatic. They find an<br />

astonishing 25% drop between 2009-10 and 2010-11 in <strong>the</strong> recorded incomes of those<br />

with incomes over £150,000.<br />

That said, <strong>the</strong>y also acknowledge <strong>the</strong> very considerable uncertainty around <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

estimates. The estimates depend on a range of assumptions about what might have<br />

happened in <strong>the</strong> absence of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, and especially on how much of <strong>the</strong> drop in<br />

recorded income is down to one-off “forestalling” – that is people taking income a year<br />

early before <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was introduced. The truth is we still do not know <strong>the</strong> true<br />

effect of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on revenues.<br />

The worry for <strong>the</strong> Chancellor is that <strong>the</strong> estimate that cutting <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> to 45% will<br />

only cost £100 million is particularly uncertain. It assumes a “no behaviour change”<br />

cost of £3 billion offset by a behavioural change of £2.9 billion. The first number we<br />

know reasonably accu<strong>rate</strong>ly; <strong>the</strong> second number is estimated with great uncertainty.<br />

Even if we knew <strong>the</strong> effect of introducing <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> – which we don’t with any<br />

precision – responses may not be symmetric. Those who have got a taste for avoiding<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> may continue to avoid <strong>the</strong> 45p <strong>rate</strong> (even if <strong>the</strong>y wouldn’t have done so<br />

had <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> never existed) …<br />

Perhaps one worry for <strong>the</strong> Chancellor as <strong>the</strong> dust settles on his third Budget is that in<br />

his attempt to achieve a fiscally neutral package he has created some risks. We know<br />

pretty much for sure that <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong> personal allowance will cost about £3.5<br />

billion in 2014-15. We do not know with anything like such certainty that <strong>the</strong> cut in <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> will cost only £100 million. We do not know that <strong>the</strong> proposed caps on <strong>tax</strong><br />

reliefs will bring in <strong>the</strong> £300 million or so <strong>the</strong> Chancellor is banking on. Nor do we know<br />

that <strong>the</strong> stamp duty changes will raise <strong>the</strong> nearly £300 million that he has pencilled in.<br />

This Budget may turn out to be less fiscally neutral than intended. 109<br />

Mr Johnson also raised <strong>the</strong>se concerns when he gave evidence to <strong>the</strong> Treasury Committee,<br />

while making <strong>the</strong> point that <strong>the</strong> department’s findings chimed with o<strong>the</strong>r studies of <strong>tax</strong>payer<br />

behaviour in similar circumstances:<br />

108 Thirtieth report: Budget 2012, 18 April 2012 HC1910-II 2012-12 Ev11<br />

109 Budget 2012- Opening remarks: Tax changes do not amount to a reform programme, Institute for Fiscal<br />

Studies, 22 March 2012. At this presentation, James Browne provided a detailed discussion of HMRC’s<br />

analysis : The <strong>50p</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, IFS 22 March 2012<br />

28


A number of things are striking about <strong>the</strong> HMRC report, <strong>the</strong> most striking of which is<br />

<strong>the</strong> scale of change in incomes of <strong>the</strong> people on over £150,000. It is extraordinary that<br />

we see a fall in <strong>the</strong>ir recorded income of 25% in <strong>the</strong> years just before and after <strong>the</strong><br />

introduction of it. The problem <strong>the</strong> HMRC had was that a lot of that was forestalling:<br />

how do you think about <strong>the</strong> counter-factual? What it has done, broadly speaking, as<br />

much as it could given <strong>the</strong> information, is try to compare what happened to <strong>the</strong><br />

incomes of people between £115,00 and £150,000, with what happened to <strong>the</strong><br />

incomes of those earning over £150,000 ...<br />

The real issue is: does it look from what it has done that its central estimate is broadly<br />

sensible? Probably, yes, but as you can back out from what it has said, it is incredibly<br />

uncertain, to <strong>the</strong> extent that we think that its estimate suggests <strong>the</strong>re is only a twothirds<br />

probability that a revenue-maximising <strong>rate</strong> lies between 30% and 75%. Those<br />

numbers are absurd in some sense, but that gives you a sense of <strong>the</strong> level of numbers<br />

of assumption and uncertainty that underlie what it has done.<br />

If that were <strong>the</strong> only thing we knew, we would be pretty sceptical that its results bore a<br />

lot and sceptical about how much weight you put on <strong>the</strong> results. The thing that makes<br />

us think that you may want to put more weight on <strong>the</strong>m is that <strong>the</strong>y are actually pretty<br />

much in line with what previous studies here and elsewhere have got. 110<br />

For its part <strong>the</strong> Committee concluded that, “<strong>the</strong> cost and benefits of reducing <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong><br />

<strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> to 45p are both highly uncertain, and could be significantly more or less than <strong>the</strong> cost<br />

included in <strong>the</strong> Budget. We recommend that HMRC publish in due course a comprehensive<br />

assessment of <strong>the</strong> effect on <strong>the</strong> Exchequer of <strong>the</strong> new 45p <strong>rate</strong>.” 111<br />

Initial reactions in <strong>the</strong> press were divided about <strong>the</strong> Chancellor’s decision. An editorial in <strong>the</strong><br />

Times argued that <strong>the</strong> change was “good for business … <strong>the</strong> new <strong>rate</strong> raises no money and<br />

deters people from bringing business here. It cannot be defended. Mr Osborne has made a<br />

political gamble, but it is <strong>the</strong> right bet for Britain.” 112 By contrast <strong>the</strong> Guardian characterised it<br />

was “an unnecessary <strong>tax</strong> cut … four months ago [at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Autumn Statement],<br />

cutting <strong>tax</strong>es for <strong>the</strong> super-rich was not what <strong>the</strong> Chancellor saw as a priority; not it’s among<br />

his top priorities. This raises one simple question: why?” 113 In an editorial before <strong>the</strong> Budget<br />

<strong>the</strong> Financial Times had argued that while “calls for its abolition from business people and<br />

Tory back bencher grow ever more insistent … <strong>the</strong> Chancellor would be wise to leave it be –<br />

at least for now”:<br />

There would be a stronger case for cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> if it could be shown that it was<br />

a significant break on <strong>the</strong> growth of <strong>the</strong> economy’s supply side. But with growth<br />

arguably suffering from a lack of demand ra<strong>the</strong>r than supply, it is hard to make this<br />

argument. And anyway, if one could make it, one would certainly not respond with a<br />

half measure like a 5p cut. 114<br />

After <strong>the</strong> Budget <strong>the</strong> paper acknowledged that “<strong>the</strong> economic case for <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> is weak<br />

… but <strong>the</strong> move risks undermining <strong>the</strong> coalition’s claim that <strong>the</strong> burden of austerity is being<br />

110 HC1910-II 2012-12 Ev24 Q171<br />

111 HC1910 2012-12 para 97<br />

112 “Leader: A <strong>50p</strong> bet on Britain”, Times, 22 March 2012<br />

113 “Editorial: George Osborne’s misplaced priorities”, Guardian, 22 March 2012<br />

114 “Editorial: Osborne’s choice and <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>”, Financial Times, 17 March 2012<br />

29


share fairly.” 115 The Economist argued that <strong>the</strong> politics of <strong>the</strong> Chancellor’s decision would be<br />

“rough, but it was <strong>the</strong> right thing to do. Because Britain specialises in high-value services<br />

such as banking, accountancy and insurance, it needs to attract <strong>the</strong> worlds brightest … this<br />

week’s change may be more symbolic than fiscal … but symbols matter.” 116 In a second<br />

article on <strong>the</strong> department’s assessment of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, <strong>the</strong> paper suggested that <strong>the</strong> future<br />

of <strong>the</strong> 45p was unlikely to be a long one:<br />

The results suggest that <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> take from incomes over £150,000 is little different<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r you set <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> at 45% or 50%. Setting <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> much higher than 45% is<br />

pointless; beyond 50% it is self-defeating. The <strong>additional</strong> revenue loss of abolishing<br />

<strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> altoge<strong>the</strong>r is estimated at a few hundred million. That is unlikely to<br />

have escaped <strong>the</strong> Chancellor’s notice. 117<br />

Writing in <strong>the</strong> journal Taxation, <strong>the</strong> magazine’s editor, Mike Truman, pointed out that <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

schedule retained <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r major change to <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> regime made by Alistair Darling<br />

in 2010: <strong>the</strong> withdrawal of <strong>the</strong> personal allowance for those on incomes over £100,000:<br />

The prize for most leaked announcement probably goes to <strong>the</strong> reduction in <strong>the</strong> 50%<br />

<strong>rate</strong> to 45%. From <strong>the</strong> pre-Budget press coverage, some might have thought that this<br />

was going to happen from 6 April 2012. It is in fact going to come in from April 2013,<br />

just like <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r changes. Indeed, where this government deserves great credit is that<br />

it has stuck to its promise that it will have a proper process of consultation on<br />

significant <strong>tax</strong> changes, leading to draft legislation issued four months before <strong>the</strong><br />

Budget.<br />

So <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> from April 2013 will be 45%, right? Wrong. There will still be an<br />

effective 60% charge on income between £100,000 and £118,200, as <strong>the</strong> personal<br />

allowance is withdrawn at a <strong>rate</strong> of £1 for every £2 of income. Exactly <strong>the</strong> same taper<br />

is seen as a candidate for simplification when applied to age allowance, so why not<br />

simplify it at <strong>the</strong> top of <strong>the</strong> income scale too? Ra<strong>the</strong>r than withdrawing personal<br />

allowances (or <strong>the</strong> nil-<strong>rate</strong> band of income <strong>tax</strong> as it should properly be described), start<br />

<strong>the</strong> 45% <strong>rate</strong> at a point which raises about <strong>the</strong> same amount in total; say about<br />

£85,000. 118<br />

Many Member raised this issue in <strong>the</strong> debates following <strong>the</strong> Budget statement; in his speech<br />

<strong>the</strong> Shadow Chancellor, Ed Balls, argued that <strong>the</strong> cut in <strong>the</strong> 45p <strong>rate</strong> would cost much more<br />

than <strong>the</strong> Government had estimated:<br />

The Chancellor tries to claim that <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> does not raise any money, and<br />

that he is raising in stamp duty and <strong>tax</strong> avoidance five times <strong>the</strong> cost of cutting <strong>the</strong> top<br />

<strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong>. But his own HMRC report makes <strong>the</strong> true position clear, in table A2 on<br />

page 51. It says that next year he will give £3.01 billion in <strong>tax</strong> cuts to existing and<br />

legitimate top <strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payers, paid more than £150,000. That is a fact. That is six times<br />

more in <strong>tax</strong> cuts to <strong>the</strong> richest than he is raising in <strong>the</strong> stamp duty and <strong>tax</strong> avoidance<br />

measures. He is gambling that this will <strong>the</strong>n bring in £2.9 billion in new <strong>tax</strong> revenues<br />

from people currently not paying <strong>tax</strong>, without any hard evidence to justify that claim—<br />

115 “Editorial: An audacious gamble from <strong>the</strong> artful Osborne”, Financial Times, 22 March 2012<br />

116 “Leader: This way, sir”, Economist, 24 March 2012<br />

117 “Falling flat : The 50% <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>”, Economist, 24 March 2012<br />

118 “Complexification”, Taxation, 22 March 2012<br />

30


an estimate that <strong>the</strong> OBR says in <strong>the</strong> Budget documentation is “highly uncertain” and<br />

could lead to a much higher cost. 119<br />

In response <strong>the</strong> Secretary of State, Vince Cable, argued that <strong>the</strong> Labour Government’s<br />

original decision to introduce <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> had been shown to be fundamentally flawed:<br />

I agree with <strong>the</strong> Chancellor that <strong>the</strong> decision to cut <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> from <strong>50p</strong> to 45p<br />

was economically <strong>the</strong> rational thing to do. I want to focus <strong>the</strong> debate not on symbols<br />

but on substance. I share <strong>the</strong> emotional reaction of <strong>the</strong> many people who are disgusted<br />

to hear pampered financiers whinging about <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong>es. On an emotional level, nobody<br />

can sympathise with that. However, we have to deal with <strong>the</strong> practical realities that<br />

were burned on my consciousness as a result of sitting in my place on <strong>the</strong> Opposition<br />

Benches for 13 years, exchanging views on <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> with successive Labour<br />

Ministers from Blair to Brown to Balls. Year after year, <strong>the</strong>y would tell <strong>the</strong> Liberal<br />

Democrats that it was economically stupid to raise <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> above 40%. That<br />

was <strong>the</strong>ir message, year after year. Then, a few weeks before <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

Government—I think it was 57 days—<strong>the</strong>y introduced <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in order to create a<br />

political dividing line. That decision had nothing whatever to do with economics. The<br />

point that <strong>the</strong>y had been making over all those years was that raising <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> in<br />

that way would raise relatively little revenue.<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong> casuistry of <strong>the</strong> shadow Chancellor’s intervention a few moments ago, in<br />

trying to argue that vast sums of money had been sacrificed, line 3 of <strong>the</strong> scorecard<br />

makes it absolutely clear that we are talking about a revenue loss of £100 million a<br />

year. That figure has been endorsed by <strong>the</strong> Office for Budget Responsibility. The<br />

changes that have been introduced in <strong>the</strong> Budget, including increased <strong>tax</strong>ation of highvalue<br />

property, plugging loopholes and much tougher anti-avoidance rules, will bring in<br />

at least five times that amount. 120<br />

At a later stage in <strong>the</strong> debates Alistair Darling, who had introduced <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> when<br />

Chancellor, argued that <strong>the</strong> inherent uncertainties in <strong>the</strong> forecasting exercise, given <strong>the</strong> size<br />

of forestalling effects, made <strong>the</strong> Government’s case for change quite weak:<br />

I want to say a word about <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong>, since I introduced it. At <strong>the</strong> time, I said it<br />

was a temporary measure. I did not particularly want to introduce it, but I took <strong>the</strong> view<br />

that, at a time when we were asking many people in this country to share <strong>the</strong> burden of<br />

meeting <strong>the</strong> increased cost of <strong>the</strong> downturn, it was right that those who had done well<br />

over <strong>the</strong> previous 10 years or so should bear <strong>the</strong>ir fair share of it. I do not have a<br />

philosophic attachment to that <strong>rate</strong> at all, <strong>the</strong>refore, but this is not a Budget in which I<br />

would have returned to <strong>the</strong> topic, simply because <strong>the</strong> incomes of many o<strong>the</strong>r people in<br />

this country are currently being squeezed and <strong>the</strong>y are going to lose out this year. I<br />

would have tried to have done something about <strong>the</strong>ir position first.<br />

The documentation that <strong>the</strong> Treasury has produced on <strong>the</strong> measure reminds me of <strong>the</strong><br />

stuff that was produced for <strong>the</strong> five tests in respect of <strong>the</strong> euro, in that so much<br />

evidence has been adduced in support of <strong>the</strong> Government position. Why did <strong>the</strong>y not<br />

just say that <strong>the</strong>y philosophically did not want <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> so <strong>the</strong>y were going to cut it?<br />

As <strong>the</strong> OBR says that its calculations are highly uncertain and it is very difficult to<br />

estimate behavioural effects, especially after only a year, and given that <strong>the</strong>re are so<br />

119 HC Deb 22 March 2012 c960. Mr Balls is referring to <strong>the</strong> ‘static’ cost of <strong>the</strong> cut in <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, that<br />

makes no allowance for any behavioural change.<br />

120 HC Deb 22 March 2012 c966<br />

31


many uncertainties and <strong>the</strong>re will be so much forestalling, it is difficult for <strong>the</strong><br />

Government to say, “Look, this wasn’t actually raising anything.”<br />

At a time like this, I think <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> brought in £1 billion and that we are<br />

talking about smaller sums in relation to some of <strong>the</strong> welfare reforms means that <strong>the</strong><br />

Government cannot simply write it off. If <strong>the</strong>y want to bring <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> down to 45p, that is<br />

fine, although I am bound to say that I have never understood <strong>the</strong> argument that<br />

someone will still work harder if <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> comes down to 45%, yet <strong>the</strong>y will also work<br />

harder if <strong>the</strong>y are told at <strong>the</strong> same time that <strong>the</strong>y will be paying five times as much <strong>tax</strong><br />

in <strong>the</strong> future. That seems a very odd argument to run. 121<br />

In HMRC’s assessment of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, it was noted that fur<strong>the</strong>r years’ data could add<br />

something to this exercise, but a definitive answer was infeasible, given <strong>the</strong> difficulties of<br />

stripping out o<strong>the</strong>r influences on incomes and <strong>tax</strong> yields:<br />

The results can only be considered an estimate of <strong>the</strong> yield in <strong>the</strong> very short term and<br />

as such may be higher than <strong>the</strong> long term yield, particularly as some behavioural<br />

responses such as <strong>the</strong> possibility that those affected might leave <strong>the</strong> UK may take<br />

place over a number of years. Similarly, <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> may have been<br />

viewed as temporary may mean that behavioural responses such as migration are<br />

smaller than if it had been a permanent change. Conversely, a temporary increase<br />

may make it more likely that individuals postpone withdrawing income from<br />

investments in anticipation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> going down, <strong>the</strong>reby increasing <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong><br />

behavioural response.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> analysis is only based on one year‟s data, this does not invalidate <strong>the</strong><br />

results. Future years‟ data may improve <strong>the</strong> reliability of estimates, although estimating<br />

what incomes and <strong>tax</strong> revenues would have been in <strong>the</strong> absence of <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

also becomes more difficult as time elapses fur<strong>the</strong>r from <strong>the</strong> „base ‟ year (<strong>the</strong> year<br />

before <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> became effective). 122<br />

As noted above, in his Budget speech <strong>the</strong> Chancellor announced a number of measures to<br />

increase <strong>tax</strong> receipts from <strong>the</strong> wealthiest <strong>tax</strong>payers, including a cap on certain unlimited<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> reliefs. This has proved quite controversial as many charities have argued a cap<br />

could have a very serious impact on <strong>the</strong> incentives for those on higher incomes to make<br />

charitable donations. In an interview with <strong>the</strong> Telegraph, Mr Osborne said he had been<br />

shown some analysis of <strong>tax</strong> returns illustrating <strong>the</strong> problem that a cap could tackle:<br />

The Chancellor personally studied <strong>the</strong> “anonymised” copies of <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> returns<br />

submitted by some of <strong>the</strong> country’s wealthiest citizens which showed some people are<br />

able to avoid paying income <strong>tax</strong> entirely. The analysis convinced Mr Osborne that<br />

millionaires must pay a minimum <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> equivalent to about a third of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

earnings, which has been described as a “tycoon <strong>tax</strong>”.<br />

Mr Osborne told The Daily Telegraph: “I was shocked to see that some of <strong>the</strong> very<br />

wealthiest people in <strong>the</strong> country have organised <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong> affairs, and to be fair it’s<br />

within <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> laws, so that <strong>the</strong>y were regularly paying virtually no income <strong>tax</strong>. And I<br />

don’t think that’s right. … I’m not allowed to be shown <strong>the</strong> names of <strong>the</strong> individuals but<br />

I’ve sat with <strong>the</strong> most senior people at <strong>the</strong> Inland Revenue, <strong>the</strong> people who run some<br />

of <strong>the</strong> high net worth units <strong>the</strong>re. They have given me examples, anonymised<br />

examples, and so we are taking action.”<br />

121 HC Deb 26 March 2012 cc1199-1200<br />

122 HMRC, March 2012 p20, pp2-3<br />

32


The report found that Britain’s 20 biggest <strong>tax</strong> avoiders have used three main loopholes<br />

to legally reduce <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>the</strong>ir income <strong>tax</strong> bills by a total of £145 million in a year. Two<br />

thirds of <strong>the</strong>m wrote off business losses in one of <strong>the</strong>ir companies against <strong>the</strong>ir income<br />

<strong>tax</strong> bill, reducing it by as much as half . Several of <strong>the</strong>m offset <strong>the</strong> cost of business<br />

mortgages or borrowing on buy-to-let properties against <strong>the</strong>ir income <strong>tax</strong> bill, while<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rs took advantage of relief on donations to charity. 123<br />

During <strong>the</strong> second reading debate on <strong>the</strong> Finance Bill on 16 April <strong>the</strong> Chief Secretary to <strong>the</strong><br />

Treasury, Danny Alexander, cited some figures showing that a small, but significant number<br />

of <strong>the</strong> very highest earners had exploited <strong>the</strong>se rules so as to pay very little <strong>tax</strong> in practice:<br />

The basic principle that <strong>the</strong> wealthiest in <strong>the</strong> land should pay a fair proportion of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

income in income <strong>tax</strong> must be absolutely right, not least because last week we<br />

published data showing that last year some of <strong>the</strong> wealthiest people in <strong>the</strong> country had<br />

reduced <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong> bills to below <strong>the</strong> basic <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> …<br />

The figures [are] based on <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> system from 2010-11, under <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> rules put in<br />

place by [<strong>the</strong> previous] … Government. They show, for example, that 6% of those<br />

earning over £10 million a year were paying <strong>tax</strong> at under 10%, that 3% were paying it<br />

at 10% to 20%, that 8% were paying it at 20% to 30%, that 12% were paying it at 30%<br />

to 40%, and that 72% were paying it at above 40%. 124<br />

The figures were widely reported in <strong>the</strong> press, though not officially published at <strong>the</strong> time; 125<br />

subsequently <strong>the</strong> Exchequer Secretary, David Gauke, set out <strong>the</strong>se estimates in answer to a<br />

number of PQs – from which <strong>the</strong> following is taken:<br />

Mr Gauke: The information requested is as follows:<br />

(i) The proportion of <strong>tax</strong>payers liable to income <strong>tax</strong> by <strong>the</strong>ir total income and average<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> are shown in <strong>the</strong> following table:<br />

Proportion (%) of individuals reporting various average <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s by total income category (2010-11)<br />

<strong>Income</strong><br />

Average <strong>tax</strong> £100,000 to £150,000 to £250,000 to £500,000 to £1,000,000 to £5,000,000 to Over<br />

<strong>rate</strong>s £150,000 £250,000 £500,000 £1,000,000 £5,000,000 £10,000,000 £10,000,000<br />

Above 40% 0 6 73 81 80 81 72<br />

30% to 40% 67 77 18 11 10 8 12<br />

20% to 30% 24 13 5 4 5 4 8<br />

10% to 20% 8 3 2 2 2 3 3<br />

Under 10% 1 2 2 2 3 4 6<br />

Figures are based on an analysis of self-assessment (SA) returns for <strong>the</strong> 2010-11 <strong>tax</strong><br />

year, as available at Budget 2012. <strong>Income</strong> bands include those with average <strong>rate</strong>s at<br />

<strong>the</strong> lower limit (e.g. a <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of exactly 30% falls in <strong>the</strong> “30% to


When <strong>the</strong> figures were first reported, Robert Peston, <strong>the</strong> BBC’s business editor suggested<br />

this put <strong>the</strong> Government’s case for cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in a new light:<br />

Today's data shows that more than 73% of those earning over £250,000 were paying<br />

an average <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> above 40% in 2010/11. And even among those earning between<br />

£5m and £10m and those earning over £10m, <strong>the</strong> proportion paying more than 40% in<br />

<strong>tax</strong> was 81% and 72% respectively.<br />

All of which implies that many tens of thousands of people were (and are) paying <strong>the</strong><br />

50% <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, and were unable to dodge it. To state <strong>the</strong> bloomin' obvious, all of those<br />

people were given a very lovely <strong>tax</strong> cut in <strong>the</strong> budget - which will doubtless add fuel to<br />

Labour's campaign that <strong>the</strong> budget rewarded <strong>the</strong> rich at <strong>the</strong> expense of <strong>the</strong> rest. Now it<br />

is possible, I suppose, that vast numbers of people artificially reduced <strong>the</strong>ir income<br />

below <strong>the</strong> threshold of £150,000 (by deferring dividends for example) to avoid <strong>the</strong> 50%<br />

<strong>rate</strong>. That is certainly <strong>the</strong> implication of HMRC's study of what was happening.<br />

But even so it is striking quite how many people paid <strong>tax</strong> greater than 40% - a<br />

proportion 10 times greater than those who succeeded in paying almost no <strong>tax</strong>. Or to<br />

put it ano<strong>the</strong>r way, perhaps <strong>the</strong> highest earners have had a slightly unfair press,<br />

because <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong>m seem to have been paying <strong>the</strong>ir proper share.it is striking<br />

quite how many people paid <strong>tax</strong> greater than 40% - a proportion 10 times greater than<br />

those who succeeded in paying almost no <strong>tax</strong>. Or to put it ano<strong>the</strong>r way, perhaps <strong>the</strong><br />

highest earners have had a slightly unfair press, because <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong>m seem to<br />

have been paying <strong>the</strong>ir proper share.” 127<br />

The Government are still planning to introduce a cap from April 2013, though this is not to<br />

apply to relief on charitable donations. 128<br />

Turning back to <strong>the</strong> second reading debate in April 2012, Owen Smith MP, speaking for <strong>the</strong><br />

Opposition, argued that <strong>the</strong>se estimates suggested that it was misleading to think that <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> had been ineffective in raising <strong>additional</strong> revenues for <strong>the</strong> Exchequer:<br />

Only this morning, we heard <strong>the</strong> Exchequer Secretary trying to justify <strong>the</strong> proposed<br />

changes on charitable giving and <strong>the</strong> 25% cap on <strong>tax</strong> relief. He did so by revealing that<br />

a handful of people in this country who earn more than £1 million and more than £10<br />

million succeed in dodging paying <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong>. There is no news in that. One would have<br />

thought that a competent Government who understood what <strong>the</strong>y were doing would<br />

have realised that <strong>the</strong> flipside of that argument was to reveal that more than 75% of<br />

higher <strong>rate</strong> <strong>tax</strong>payers—those paying 40% and 50%—do pay all of <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong>es….<br />

Page 52 of <strong>the</strong> review by Her Majesty’s Revenue and Customs of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, in table<br />

A2 … states in black and white that £3 billion a year will be forgone as a result of <strong>the</strong><br />

changes, not <strong>the</strong> £100 million figure that is arrived at with smoke and mirrors about <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>tax</strong>able income elasticity calculation that Treasury Ministers signed off. What does <strong>the</strong><br />

Office for Budget Responsibility say about that? … It says that <strong>the</strong>re is huge<br />

uncertainty about that calculation. We contend that we should rely on <strong>the</strong> absolute<br />

numbers, as revealed this morning—that £1 billion was raised from <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> last<br />

year, not <strong>the</strong> nonsense £100 million figure. 129<br />

127 “More than 70% of high earners paid 50% <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>”, BBC News online, 16 April 2012<br />

128 For details see, <strong>Income</strong> <strong>tax</strong> – cap on unlimited reliefs, Library standard note SN6303, 28 March 2013.<br />

129 HC Deb 16 April 2012 cc127-8<br />

34


In response <strong>the</strong> Exchequer Secretary David Gauke argued that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> had proved a<br />

particularly poor way of raising money from <strong>the</strong> wealthiest <strong>tax</strong>payers:<br />

What is <strong>the</strong> effect of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>? We have <strong>the</strong> assessment of HMRC. What has <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> achieved? More people work overseas; total income has fallen by between<br />

£2.9 billion and £4.4 billion; and GDP is between 0.2% and 0.3% lower. … Both<br />

HMRC and <strong>the</strong> OBR have made a central estimate, and that is what we have used. I<br />

am sorry it does not fit into Labour’s ideology, but <strong>the</strong> reality is that HMRC’s<br />

assessment is that <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> raised less than half <strong>the</strong> expected amount and might<br />

even have cost <strong>the</strong> Exchequer. The OBR’s assessment is that it is a reasonable and<br />

central estimate.<br />

It takes a special kind of incompetence to produce a policy that sends a terrible signal<br />

to our competitors, drives higher earners out of <strong>the</strong> country, damages GDP and fails to<br />

raise revenue. There are better ways of raising revenue from <strong>the</strong> wealthy—for<br />

instance, by addressing SDLT avoidance, raising <strong>the</strong> SDLT <strong>rate</strong> on properties worth<br />

more than £2 million and capping reliefs to ensure that <strong>the</strong> wealthy cannot opt out of<br />

income <strong>tax</strong>. Both sides of <strong>the</strong> House want to raise more money from wealthy people.<br />

The reality is that we are better at doing it. 130<br />

There has been less discussion of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> recently, 131 though in <strong>the</strong>ir Green Budget<br />

published in February 2013 <strong>the</strong> IFS noted that, although “much uncertainty” remained over<br />

its impact on revenues, “several things are clear”:<br />

First, even on <strong>the</strong> Treasury’s original assumptions, raising <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> to <strong>50p</strong><br />

would have had major behavioural effects. Second, HMRC’s analysis quite clearly<br />

demonst<strong>rate</strong>s significant amounts of behavioural change by affected individuals, and<br />

especially <strong>the</strong> shifting of incomes between years (‘forestalling’). Such large distortions<br />

to behaviour are indicative of an economically inefficient <strong>tax</strong> and remind us that it is<br />

important not to fixate simply on how much <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> raised (or cost) and how much<br />

<strong>the</strong> move back to 45p will cost (or raise). There are likely to be better ways of raising<br />

money from a similar group of high-income individuals that entail less avoidance or<br />

distortion to economic activity than a <strong>50p</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> 132<br />

In contrast <strong>the</strong>re has been a great deal of discussion about income <strong>tax</strong> for those on lower<br />

incomes, first in connection with <strong>the</strong> Government’s approach to substantially increasing <strong>the</strong><br />

personal allowance in each of its first three Budgets, 133 and second, with a recent speech by<br />

<strong>the</strong> Labour leader, Ed Miliband, in which he stated that a Labour Government would<br />

reintroduce a 10p starting <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong>, funded by an annual levy on residential<br />

property – a ‘mansions <strong>tax</strong>’. 134 These differing approaches were <strong>the</strong> subject of an Opposition<br />

Day debate on 12 March, when Members also touched on <strong>the</strong> anticipated cut in <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. Opening <strong>the</strong> debate for <strong>the</strong> Opposition, Chris Leslie contrasted <strong>the</strong><br />

Government’s approach to reforming <strong>tax</strong> credits and social security benefits with <strong>the</strong> impact<br />

of <strong>the</strong> 45% <strong>rate</strong> for those on <strong>the</strong> very highest incomes:<br />

130 HC Deb 16 April 2012 c131. Similar arguments were made when provision in <strong>the</strong> Bill to set <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s of<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> from 2013 were debated two days later by <strong>the</strong> Committee of <strong>the</strong> Whole House (HC Deb 18 April<br />

2012 cc327-8). The clause was approved by 323 votes to 256.<br />

131 HMRC’s assessment of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> has been cited in answer to some PQs on this issue: for example, HC<br />

Deb 10 January 2013 cc427-8W & 22 January 2013 cc 144-5W.<br />

132 “Chapter 7: Tax and welfare reforms planned for 2013/14”, IFS Green Budget 2013, February 2013 p193.<br />

Chapter 9 of <strong>the</strong> report discusses various options for increasing <strong>tax</strong> receipts from <strong>the</strong> rich.<br />

133 As noted, for more details see, Library standard note SN6569, 25 March 2013.<br />

134 The proposal for a ‘mansions <strong>tax</strong>’ is discussed in, Land value <strong>tax</strong>ation, Library standard note SN6558, 28 June<br />

2013 pp15-20.<br />

35


Let us consider <strong>the</strong> contrast that now exists as a result of Government decisions.<br />

Those who are on low and middle incomes—that is, <strong>the</strong> vast majority of <strong>the</strong> British<br />

public—have seen <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong> credits cut, <strong>the</strong>ir child benefits squeezed, <strong>the</strong>ir cost of living<br />

rise as a result of higher VAT and <strong>the</strong>ir wages fall in real terms. However, <strong>the</strong> richest<br />

1%, including <strong>the</strong> lucky few who earn £1 million a year, will see an average <strong>tax</strong> cut of<br />

£100,000 in four weeks’ time, and banking executives will not have to pay that<br />

annoying bonus <strong>tax</strong>, all thanks to <strong>the</strong> Chancellor’s generosity. 135<br />

As part of his response to <strong>the</strong> debate, <strong>the</strong> Exchequer Secretary, David Gauke, reite<strong>rate</strong>d <strong>the</strong><br />

Government’s case for cutting <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>:<br />

Let me say something that I hope is not controversial: <strong>the</strong> principal purpose of income<br />

<strong>tax</strong> is to raise revenue. So we commissioned HMRC to analyse just how effective <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was in raising revenue.<br />

That HMRC report, laid before <strong>the</strong> House, set out thorough and compelling evidence<br />

on <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. It showed that <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was uncompetitive, distortive and<br />

inefficient. Not only did it not raise much revenue, but it could even have cost <strong>the</strong><br />

Exchequer money when <strong>the</strong> indirect impacts on o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>tax</strong>es were taken into account.<br />

This Government were not prepared to maintain a <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> that was both<br />

ineffective at raising money and that left us with <strong>the</strong> highest statutory <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong><br />

in <strong>the</strong> G20, so we acted, in <strong>the</strong> interests of <strong>the</strong> country, and <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> will fall to<br />

45p from April this year. This will see our top <strong>rate</strong> of <strong>tax</strong> drop below that of Australia,<br />

Germany, Japan and Canada, which will send a signal to businesses taking decisions<br />

on investment and location that <strong>the</strong> UK is a competitive environment. 136<br />

The 2013 Budget did not see any change in <strong>the</strong> Government’s plans to cut <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

to 45% from April 2013, though a written answer after <strong>the</strong> Budget gives updated estimates of<br />

<strong>the</strong> amounts raised by <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong>, and its projected yield had it been sustained: 137<br />

Asked by Baroness Miller of Hendon: To ask Her Majesty's Government what was<br />

<strong>the</strong> (1) forecast, and (2) actual, <strong>tax</strong> yield at <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong> band for fiscal year 2011-12,<br />

and what is <strong>the</strong> forecast <strong>tax</strong> yield at <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong> band for 2012-13.<br />

Lord Deighton: Estimates of <strong>tax</strong> liabilities at <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> are<br />

published in Table 2.6 "<strong>Income</strong> <strong>tax</strong> liabilities, by income source and <strong>tax</strong> band, from<br />

2010-11 to 2012-13" on HM Revenue and Customs' (HMRC) website 1 , set out at <strong>the</strong><br />

end of this answer.<br />

Statistics are based on <strong>the</strong> 2010-11 Survey of Personal <strong>Income</strong>s (SPI) projected in-line<br />

with <strong>the</strong> Office for Budget Responsibility's (OBR) Autumn 2012 Economic and fiscal<br />

outlook for future years. Statistics based on 2011-12 outturn data and <strong>the</strong> OBR's March<br />

2013 projections are not yet available.<br />

It is not possible to infer <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> yield from <strong>the</strong> imposition of <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong> from<br />

<strong>the</strong>se statistics. However, HMRC's report "The Exchequer effect of <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>additional</strong><br />

135 HC Deb 12 March 2013 c162. The Labour Party have claimed that 13,000 individuals with incomes over £1m<br />

will receive an annual <strong>tax</strong> cut worth £100,000 from a 45% <strong>rate</strong>. This is based on HMRC’s projected figures for<br />

total incomes and <strong>tax</strong> liabilities, by income range, for 2012/13 (National Statistics: Table 2.5), and is examined<br />

in a recent post by FullFact (“Are 13,000 millionaires getting a £100,000 <strong>tax</strong> cut?”, 27 February 2013).<br />

136 op.cit. c181<br />

137 HL Deb 27 March 2013 cc252-3WA. See also, HL Deb 24 June 2013 cc500-2.<br />

36


ate of income <strong>tax</strong>" provides an estimate of this. This showed that <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> raised far<br />

less revenue than originally expected. The report is available on HMRC's website 2 .<br />

Current and previous estimates of <strong>additional</strong> revenue from <strong>the</strong> 50% income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

can be found in <strong>the</strong> Office for Budget Responsibility's March 2012 Economic and Fiscal<br />

Outlook report, "Box 4.2: The <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong>" 3 .<br />

This has been recreated in <strong>the</strong> following table:<br />

£ billion<br />

Outturn Forecast<br />

Liabilities Basis 2009-10 2010-11 2011-12 2012-13 2013-14 2014-15 2015-16<br />

Underlying Impact 0.0 2.5 2.5 2.7 2.9 3.2 3.5<br />

of <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>: Original Estimate,<br />

OBR estimate June 2010 (TIE=0.35)<br />

Current Costing1 0.0 0.7 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.8<br />

Difference 0.0 -1.8 -1.9 -2.1 -2.2 -2.5 -2.7<br />

1<br />

Based on <strong>the</strong> current estimated cost of a reduction in <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> from 50 per to 40%.<br />

Key:<br />

- negligible<br />

. not applicable<br />

Footnotes for table 2.6<br />

37


(1) Taxpayers with no <strong>tax</strong>able earnings and total <strong>tax</strong>able income from savings below <strong>the</strong> starting <strong>rate</strong> limit.<br />

(2) Taxpayers with no <strong>tax</strong>able earnings and total <strong>tax</strong>able income from savings between <strong>the</strong> starting <strong>rate</strong> limit and <strong>the</strong><br />

basic <strong>rate</strong> limit and/or dividends at <strong>the</strong> 10p ordinary <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

(3) Taxpayers with total <strong>tax</strong>able income below <strong>the</strong> basic <strong>rate</strong> limit.<br />

(4) For 2009-10 <strong>tax</strong>payers with total <strong>tax</strong>able income above <strong>the</strong> basic <strong>rate</strong> limit. From 2010-11onwards <strong>tax</strong>payers with<br />

total <strong>tax</strong>able income between <strong>the</strong> basic <strong>rate</strong> limit and <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> limit.<br />

(5) Taxpayers with total <strong>tax</strong>able income above <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>rate</strong> limit.<br />

(6) In this context <strong>tax</strong> reductions refer to allowances given at a fixed <strong>rate</strong>, for example <strong>the</strong> Married Couples Allowance.<br />

(7) Projected estimates based upon <strong>the</strong> 2010-11 Survey of Personal <strong>Income</strong>s using economic assumptions consistent<br />

with <strong>the</strong> OBR's December 2012 economic and fiscal outlook. These projections fall outside <strong>the</strong> scope of National<br />

Statistics.<br />

1 http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/statistics/<strong>tax</strong>-statistics/table2-6.pdf<br />

2 http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/budget2012/excheq-income-<strong>tax</strong>-2042.pdf<br />

3 http://budgetresponsibility.independent.gov.uk/wordpress/docs/March-2012-EFO1.pdf<br />

The Chancellor did not discuss <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in his 2013 Budget speech, though <strong>the</strong><br />

Budget report noted that <strong>the</strong> very wealthiest individuals will continue to pay a large share of<br />

all income <strong>tax</strong> receipts:<br />

Over a quarter of all income <strong>tax</strong> is paid by just 1 per cent of <strong>tax</strong>payers, with <strong>the</strong> top 5<br />

per cent paying around half of all income <strong>tax</strong> … Since 2010, <strong>the</strong> Government has<br />

raised <strong>tax</strong>es on <strong>the</strong> rich in every Budget: Budget 2010 increased higher <strong>rate</strong> capital<br />

gains <strong>tax</strong>; Budget 2011 tackled avoidance through disguised remuneration; Budget<br />

2012 raised stamp duty on high-value homes; Autumn Statement 2012 took action to<br />

reduce <strong>the</strong> cost of pensions <strong>tax</strong> relief; and Budget 2013 announces fur<strong>the</strong>r measures<br />

that tackle offshore <strong>tax</strong> evasion by high earners. The revenue raised from <strong>the</strong>se<br />

measures will offset many times over <strong>the</strong> small cost of just over £100 million from <strong>the</strong><br />

reduction in <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> from 50 per cent to 45 per cent. 138<br />

<strong>Income</strong> <strong>tax</strong> is an annual <strong>tax</strong>, so that <strong>the</strong> annual Finance Bill has to make provision for <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong><br />

to be levied each year. Clause 1 of <strong>the</strong> Finance Bill 2013 imposes <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> for 2013/14, and<br />

<strong>the</strong> clause was one of those selected for debate on <strong>the</strong> floor of <strong>the</strong> House, at <strong>the</strong> start of <strong>the</strong><br />

Bill’s Committee stage. On this occasion <strong>the</strong> Opposition put down an amendment to require<br />

<strong>the</strong> Government to review <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> new 45p <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong>; Ca<strong>the</strong>rine McKinnell, <strong>the</strong><br />

Shadow Exchequer Secretary, set out <strong>the</strong> party’s position as follows:<br />

What we got in this year’s Budget, and in <strong>the</strong> very first clause of <strong>the</strong> Finance Bill, is <strong>the</strong><br />

coalition’s unjustifiable and grossly unfair decision to reduce <strong>the</strong> top <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong><br />

from <strong>50p</strong> to 45p, a cut that benefits just 267,000 people earning more than £150,000,<br />

13,000 of whom are lucky enough to earn more than £1 million. Indeed, those lucky<br />

few are receiving an average <strong>tax</strong> cut of a whopping £107,000 according to HMRC<br />

figures …<br />

We have made it perfectly clear from day one that we do not support <strong>the</strong> cut to <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> now, and we call on <strong>the</strong> Government to analyse <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> introduction and<br />

premature removal of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. When we come to publish our next manifesto, we<br />

will review <strong>the</strong> state of <strong>the</strong> economy and whe<strong>the</strong>r a <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> would be <strong>the</strong> right<br />

response. I hope that Members of o<strong>the</strong>r Opposition parties, as well as Liberal<br />

Democrats, will support our amendment, because it would help to establish whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> would bring in <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> Exchequer revenue that was anticipated—but<br />

if <strong>the</strong> Government refuse to back it today, we will never know. 139<br />

138 HC 1033, March 2013 para 1.202-3. For more data on <strong>the</strong> distribution of income <strong>tax</strong> receipts see, HMRC,<br />

National Statistics: Shares of total income … and income <strong>tax</strong> (Table 2.4), April 2013.<br />

139 HC Deb 18 April 2013 c508, c512<br />

38


In response <strong>the</strong> Exchequer Secretary, David Gauke, argued, “<strong>the</strong> fact is that a <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was<br />

no effective”:<br />

HMRC published a thorough and very well-researched report at Budget 2012 that<br />

showed <strong>the</strong> effect of <strong>the</strong> <strong>additional</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong>. Those matters were debated at<br />

considerable length last year and <strong>the</strong> report shows that <strong>the</strong> <strong>rate</strong> was not raising <strong>the</strong><br />

money that <strong>the</strong> previous Government intended it to raise. It is illogical to maintain a <strong>tax</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> that is not effective at raising revenue from high earners and that risks damaging<br />

growth. We have found better ways of raising money from <strong>the</strong> wealthy that raise more<br />

money but do less damage to <strong>the</strong> economy.<br />

We always keep <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s under review ... It seems to me that <strong>the</strong> purpose of <strong>the</strong><br />

amendment is not just to enable us to have ano<strong>the</strong>r debate on <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> today but<br />

to enable <strong>the</strong> Labour party to find an escape route from its policy. Until a few days ago,<br />

it was against getting rid of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. Labour will not answer <strong>the</strong> question, however,<br />

of what it will do at <strong>the</strong> next election. Its holding position is clearly that it will have a<br />

review. 140<br />

140 op.cit. cc535-6. In <strong>the</strong> event <strong>the</strong> amendment was negatived by 264 votes to 203 (c537).<br />

39


Appendix: Discussion of <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> in <strong>the</strong> Mirrlees Review<br />

In September 2011 <strong>the</strong> Institute for Fiscal Studies FS published a major review of <strong>the</strong> UK <strong>tax</strong><br />

system, which had been chaired by Sir James Mirrlees. 1<strong>41</strong><br />

A central <strong>the</strong>me to <strong>the</strong> review was that politicians and policy-makers needed to consider <strong>the</strong><br />

system as a whole. Certainly whatever <strong>the</strong> merits of <strong>the</strong> debate <strong>the</strong>re has been over <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong>, supporters and critics have tended to discuss it in isolation. While <strong>the</strong> Mirrlees Review<br />

did not make any particular recommendations about <strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> <strong>rate</strong> itself, in <strong>the</strong>ir examination<br />

of <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong>ation of earnings, <strong>the</strong> authors discussed <strong>the</strong> work that had been done on <strong>the</strong> money<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>50p</strong> might raise, before making some wider points about <strong>tax</strong>ing <strong>the</strong> wealthiest in society.<br />

An extract is reproduced below: 142 *<br />

From 2010–11 a new 50% <strong>rate</strong> of income <strong>tax</strong> applies to incomes above £150,000. The<br />

government estimates that this directly affects only 275,000 individuals, out of an adult<br />

population of about 49 million. Yet <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> applying to <strong>the</strong> very highest earners<br />

has an importance out of proportion to <strong>the</strong>ir numbers, simply because <strong>the</strong>y are such an<br />

important source of revenue: even before this reform took effect, almost a quarter of income<br />

<strong>tax</strong> was paid by <strong>the</strong> top 1% of income <strong>tax</strong> payers, just over 300,000. 143 That is a fact worth<br />

repeating. Almost one pound in every four collected by <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> system comes from<br />

just 1% of income <strong>tax</strong> payers. Of course this largely reflects just how much more pre-<strong>tax</strong><br />

income <strong>the</strong> top 1% of <strong>tax</strong>payers earn than <strong>the</strong> bulk of <strong>the</strong> population do.<br />

As noted in <strong>the</strong> previous chapter, <strong>the</strong> responsiveness of <strong>tax</strong>able income, and hence <strong>tax</strong><br />

receipts, to <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s may be quite high at <strong>the</strong> top of <strong>the</strong> earnings distribution—not because<br />

high earners’ employment decisions or hours of work are particularly responsive, but<br />

because <strong>the</strong>y may find o<strong>the</strong>r ways to minimise <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>tax</strong> <strong>the</strong>y pay: by reducing <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

effort per hour worked or by, for example, changing <strong>the</strong> form of <strong>the</strong>ir remuneration,<br />

contributing more to a pension or to charity, converting income into capital gains, setting<br />

<strong>the</strong>mselves up as a company, investing in <strong>tax</strong> avoidance, illegally hiding <strong>the</strong>ir income, or<br />

even leaving <strong>the</strong> country altoge<strong>the</strong>r (or not coming when <strong>the</strong>y o<strong>the</strong>rwise would have). In fact,<br />

it is not clear whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong> will raise any revenue at all.<br />

There are numerous ways in which people might reduce <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>tax</strong>able incomes in response to<br />

higher <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s; at some point, increasing <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s starts to cost money instead of raising it.<br />

The question is where is that point? Brewer, Saez and Shephard (2010) 144 address precisely<br />

this question for <strong>the</strong> highest-income 1%. Their central estimate is that <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong>able income<br />

elasticity for this group is 0.46, which implies a revenue-maximising <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on earned<br />

1<strong>41</strong> The review is available online here: http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesReview<br />

142 “Chapter 4: Reforming <strong>the</strong> Taxation of Earnings in <strong>the</strong> UK” in, Tax By Design: <strong>the</strong> Mirrlees Review, September<br />

2011 pp 108-110<br />

143 Sources: For <strong>the</strong> number facing <strong>the</strong> 50% income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>—HMRC statistics, table 2.1; for <strong>the</strong> top 1%’s share of income <strong>tax</strong><br />

revenue—HMRC statistics, table 2.4,; for total population—ONS 2008-based national population projections,; for <strong>the</strong><br />

number of dependent children in <strong>the</strong> population—HMRC, Child Benefit Statistics: Geographical Analysis, August 2010.<br />

144 Brewer, M., Saez, E., and Shephard, A. (2010), ‘Means-Testing and Tax Rates on Earnings’, in J. Mirrlees, et<br />

al., Dimensions of Tax Design: The Mirrlees Review, Oxford: OUP Institute for Fiscal Studies.<br />

40


income of 56%. 145 This in turn (accounting for NICs and indirect <strong>tax</strong>es) corresponds to an<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> of 40%: <strong>the</strong> introduction of <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong> would actually reduce revenue. 146<br />

However, <strong>the</strong>re is no escaping <strong>the</strong> uncertainty around <strong>the</strong> estimate of a 40% revenuemaximising<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>. It was based primarily on what happened to incomes when <strong>tax</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong>s changed in <strong>the</strong> late 1980s; but people’s ability to respond to <strong>tax</strong> changes may well have<br />

changed since <strong>the</strong>n. Increases in international mobility and in <strong>the</strong> availability of complicated<br />

financial products may have increased people’s scope to respond, while a succession of antiavoidance<br />

measures may have reduced it. Changes to capital gains <strong>tax</strong> have at different<br />

times made it easier and harder to escape <strong>tax</strong> by converting income into capital gains. And<br />

<strong>the</strong> government increased <strong>the</strong> likely yield of <strong>the</strong> 50% income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> by also announcing a<br />

limit on <strong>the</strong> <strong>tax</strong> relief that high earners can obtain by saving <strong>the</strong>ir income in a pension. So <strong>the</strong><br />

elasticity might have risen or fallen. And even if nothing had changed since <strong>the</strong> late 1980s,<br />

statistically <strong>the</strong>re was only a two-thirds chance that <strong>the</strong> revenue-maximising <strong>rate</strong> was<br />

somewhere between 33% and 57%. 147<br />

So we do not know with confidence what <strong>the</strong> revenue-maximising top <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> is. But<br />

governments do not have <strong>the</strong> luxury of stopping <strong>the</strong>re: policy must be decided, so in <strong>the</strong><br />

absence of compelling evidence <strong>the</strong>y must take a best guess. The Treasury’s best guess is<br />

that <strong>the</strong> 50% <strong>rate</strong> will raise some revenue. That is certainly not impossible, but it certainly<br />

uncertain.<br />

Whatever <strong>the</strong> precise revenue-maximising <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong>, it seems unlikely that much <strong>additional</strong><br />

revenue can be raised simply by increasing <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> for this group. But this is not<br />

<strong>the</strong> only tool available for extracting money from this group. Widening <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong> base—<br />

removing reliefs and clamping down on avoidance—not only raises money directly but also<br />

reduces <strong>the</strong> scope for shifting income into <strong>tax</strong>-free forms and <strong>the</strong>reby makes <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

increases more effective revenue-raisers. And <strong>the</strong>re are, of course, o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>tax</strong>es aimed at <strong>the</strong><br />

wealthy (notably inheritance <strong>tax</strong>), which might have <strong>the</strong> potential to raise revenue.<br />

In addition, we should not forget that <strong>the</strong> revenue-maximizing <strong>rate</strong> is itself not necessarily <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> that we should impose on this group. If we value <strong>the</strong>ir welfare at all, or have concerns<br />

over long-term behavioural effects, <strong>the</strong>n we might want a <strong>rate</strong> below <strong>the</strong> revenue-maximizing<br />

<strong>rate</strong> in any case.<br />

145 Brewer, M., and Browne, J. (2009), Can More Revenue Be Raised by Increasing <strong>Income</strong> Tax Rates for <strong>the</strong><br />

Very Rich?, IFS (Institute for Fiscal Studies) Briefing Note 84 (http://www.ifs.org.uk/publications/4486).<br />

146 Increases in <strong>rate</strong>s of NICs and VAT announced since this analysis was done will fur<strong>the</strong>r reduce <strong>the</strong> income <strong>tax</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> that corresponds to a given overall <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> on earnings.<br />

147 Brewer, M., and Browne, J. (2009). The estimate of <strong>the</strong> revenue-maximising top <strong>tax</strong> <strong>rate</strong> also relies on two<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r debatable assumptions. The first is that, were it not for <strong>tax</strong> changes, <strong>the</strong> incomes of <strong>the</strong> top 1% would<br />

have evolved in <strong>the</strong> same way as those of <strong>the</strong> next richest 4%, which we cannot know. The second is that any<br />

reduction in <strong>tax</strong>able income would be matched one-for-one by a reduction in spending (and <strong>the</strong>refore indirect<br />

<strong>tax</strong> revenues)—likely to be broadly accu<strong>rate</strong> if <strong>the</strong> reduced <strong>tax</strong>able income reflected a real reduction in<br />

economic activity in <strong>the</strong> UK (less work effort or less net immigration, for example), but not if it reflected more<br />

<strong>tax</strong> avoidance or evasion, say.<br />

<strong>41</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!