AFRICANUS Vol 30 No 2 ISSN 0304-615X - University of South Africa
AFRICANUS Vol 30 No 2 ISSN 0304-615X - University of South Africa
AFRICANUS Vol 30 No 2 ISSN 0304-615X - University of South Africa
You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles
YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.
<strong>AFRICANUS</strong><br />
<strong>Vol</strong> <strong>30</strong> <strong>No</strong> 2 <strong>ISSN</strong> 0<strong>30</strong>4-<strong>615X</strong>
<strong>AFRICANUS</strong> is an annual journal published for the Department <strong>of</strong> Development Administration by the<br />
<strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. It seeks to publish articles, research reports, book reviews and bibliographies<br />
on subjects relating to developmental problems and strategies in the Third World.<br />
The attention <strong>of</strong> contributors is drawn to the <strong>No</strong>te to contributors printed on page 101.<br />
Copies <strong>of</strong> <strong>AFRICANUS</strong> can be ordered from the Business Section, Unisa Press, Unisa, PO Box 392,<br />
Unisa, 0003, at R15,00 (VAT inclusive) or ($5,00) each. Cheques or postal orders should be made out in<br />
favour <strong>of</strong> the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>.<br />
The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in any article, book review or research note are<br />
those <strong>of</strong> the authors and do not necessarily represent the views and policies <strong>of</strong> Unisa or the Department <strong>of</strong><br />
Development Administration. Neither the <strong>University</strong> nor the Department guarantees the accuracy <strong>of</strong> the<br />
data included in <strong>AFRICANUS</strong> or accepts any responsibility whatsoever for any consequences <strong>of</strong> its use.<br />
Research notes present preliminary and unpublished results <strong>of</strong> the author's research and are published<br />
to afford the opportunity <strong>of</strong> gaining information and feedback from fellow researchers; citation from these<br />
should take account <strong>of</strong> their provisional character.<br />
The material in this publication is protected by copyright. Requests for permission to reproduce portions <strong>of</strong><br />
it should be sent to the Editor or to the Head: Unisa Press <strong>of</strong> the <strong>University</strong>.<br />
Set, printed and published by the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, 2000.<br />
INDEXED IN: SOCIAL SCIENCES INDEX; ULRICH'S INTERNATIONAL PERIODICALS DIRECTORY;<br />
AFRICAN URBAN & REGIONAL SCIENCE INDEX.<br />
# All rights reserved.<br />
STATEMENT BY THE DEPARTMENT OF DEVELOPMENT<br />
ADMINISTRATION<br />
The values underlying our teaching <strong>of</strong><br />
our subject are as follows:<br />
. We are dedicated to upholding human<br />
rights, an open society and<br />
social justice.<br />
. We want to move our subject to a<br />
relevant position abreast <strong>of</strong> the contemporary<br />
sociopolitical situation in<br />
<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> and the rest <strong>of</strong> the Third<br />
World.<br />
. We affirm a pragmatic and human<br />
view <strong>of</strong> development administration<br />
and we reject a technicist approach<br />
to development.<br />
. We want to direct attention to the<br />
sociopolitical climate for change and<br />
the rules <strong>of</strong> the game within which<br />
development at the local level takes<br />
place.<br />
. We affirm that development occurs<br />
when social forces are generated at<br />
the bottom <strong>of</strong> society.<br />
. We see development as a popular<br />
process not under the control <strong>of</strong><br />
external structures.<br />
. We want to engage with the popular<br />
development process in the larger<br />
society and, within that framework,<br />
with administration-related topics.<br />
With the above values, we wish to<br />
approach our subject <strong>of</strong> development<br />
administration primarily through the<br />
study <strong>of</strong> the dynamics <strong>of</strong> society in its<br />
sociopolitical context.
Journal <strong>of</strong> Development Administration<br />
<strong>Vol</strong> <strong>30</strong> <strong>No</strong> 2 2000<br />
EDITOR<br />
Naas du Plessis<br />
ASSISTANT EDITOR<br />
Linda Cornwell<br />
EDITORIAL COMMITTEE<br />
Frik de Beer<br />
Moipone Rakolojane<br />
Peter Stewart<br />
EDITORIAL ADVISORY BOARD<br />
Jan K Coetzee ± Rhodes <strong>University</strong><br />
Richard Cornwell ± Institute for Security Studies<br />
Cristo de Coning ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Witwatersrand (P & DM)<br />
O P Dwivedi ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Guelph<br />
Des Gasper ± Institute <strong>of</strong> Social Studies (The Hague)<br />
Pieter le Roux ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Western Cape<br />
Tom Lodge ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Witwatersrand<br />
Johny Matshabaphalo ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> the <strong>No</strong>rth<br />
Tsitse Monaheng ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>No</strong>rth-West<br />
Aubrey Redlinghuis ± Rand Afrikaans <strong>University</strong><br />
Michael Stocking ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> East Anglia<br />
Francois Theron ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Stellenbosch<br />
Kees van der Waal ± Rand Afrikaans <strong>University</strong><br />
Malcolm Wallis ± <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Durban-Westville
Contents<br />
Editorial 5<br />
Informal collection: a matter <strong>of</strong> survival amongst the urban<br />
vulnerable<br />
Michelle McLean<br />
8<br />
The role <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government in the development process 27<br />
David Mmakola<br />
Indicators for indigenous financial efforts: theory, evidence and<br />
prospects<br />
Jaco Vermaak<br />
Gender relations: a missing link in Third World development<br />
planning<br />
Tsepiso Mohapi<br />
On the relationship between participatory research and participatory<br />
development<br />
Naude Malan<br />
Revenue and ownership Ð the impact <strong>of</strong> privatisation in <strong>South</strong><br />
<strong>Africa</strong>: lessons from the UK<br />
Charles C Okeahalam and Royson M Mukwena<br />
38<br />
50<br />
64<br />
76<br />
3
Book Reviews<br />
Can the poor influence poverty? Participatory poverty assessments<br />
in the developing world by Caroline M Robb, Washington<br />
DC: The World Bank, 1999...<br />
Naas du Plessis<br />
Expectations <strong>of</strong> modernity: myths and meanings <strong>of</strong> urban life on<br />
the Zambian copperbelt by James Ferguson, Berkely: <strong>University</strong><br />
<strong>of</strong> California Press, 1999...<br />
Peter Stewart<br />
96<br />
98<br />
4
Editorial<br />
As globalisation is making its importance increasingly felt on the development<br />
debate, local issues become more important within this increasingly complex<br />
and diverse debate. The articles in this edition <strong>of</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>nus focus on these<br />
relevant issues and give the development practitioner and the academic food<br />
for thought.<br />
Michelle McLean's paper is based on her personal observations <strong>of</strong> the appearance<br />
and subsequent increase <strong>of</strong> informal collectors in the residential area<br />
<strong>of</strong> Glenwood/Berea, Durban. The aim <strong>of</strong> the study was to gather information<br />
from the collectors and their activities in order to help find solutions to a growing<br />
informal sector that needs to be accommodated.<br />
The article by David Mmakola explores options that could be considered in<br />
structuring a metropolitan form <strong>of</strong> local government in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, as well as<br />
the contribution that metropolitan local government could make in the development<br />
process. It further traces the origins <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government in<br />
developing countries, using Asia as an example.<br />
Jaco Vermaak in his paper evaluates indigenous financial efforts (IFEs) in rural<br />
areas in terms <strong>of</strong> their contribution to rural community development. He argues<br />
that IFEs are <strong>of</strong>ten associated and evaluated with quantitative oriteria in spite <strong>of</strong><br />
the pr<strong>of</strong>ound non-economic benefits such schemes have for community development.<br />
Evidence from successful cases <strong>of</strong> IFEs in the developing world and<br />
fieldwork done in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> are presented.<br />
In her article Tsepiso Mohapi attempts to highlight the implications <strong>of</strong> planned<br />
development for women since the 1950s when development planning first ap-<br />
5 <strong>Africa</strong>nus <strong>30</strong>(2)2000
peared internationally. The purpose <strong>of</strong> her paper, is an attempt to contribute to<br />
the resolution <strong>of</strong> mainstreaming gender into development planning.<br />
Naude Malan examines the connection between participatory development<br />
and participatory research. He argues that participation in research is not sufficient<br />
to bring about participatory development. In his article he scrutinises<br />
those aspects <strong>of</strong> development in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> that would have a decisive influence<br />
on the outcomes <strong>of</strong> participatory intervention.<br />
Charles Okeahalam and Royson Mukwena use anecdotal evidence from the<br />
United Kingdom to suggest that one <strong>of</strong> the most trusted ways <strong>of</strong> ensuring the<br />
long-term development and growth prospects <strong>of</strong> the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n economy is<br />
to develop the philosophy <strong>of</strong> the shareholder amongst all <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>ns via a<br />
carefully planned and implemented privatisation programme. The paper concentrates<br />
on two aspects <strong>of</strong> privatisation: the impact on government revenues<br />
and the impact on share ownership by employees.<br />
Book reviews by Peter Stewart and Naas du Plessis conclude the issue.<br />
NOTES ON CONTRIBUTORS<br />
Michelle McLean lectures in the Department <strong>of</strong> Physiology at the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />
Natal.<br />
Devid Mmakola is a policy analyst at the Development Bank <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong>ern<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>.<br />
Jaco Vermaak lectures in the Department <strong>of</strong> Public and Development Administration<br />
at the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Venda.<br />
Tsepiso Mohapi is a documantation assistant in the Institute <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong>ern<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>n Studies at the National <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Lesotho.<br />
Naude Malan is a lecturer in the Department <strong>of</strong> Development Studies at the<br />
Rand Afrikaans <strong>University</strong>.<br />
Charles Okeahalam is Donald Gordon Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Banking and Finance at<br />
the Graduate School <strong>of</strong> Business Administration at the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Witwatersrand.<br />
6
Royson Mukwena lectures in the Department <strong>of</strong> Public Administration at the<br />
<strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Namibia.<br />
Peter Stewart and Naas du Plessis are both lecturers in the Department <strong>of</strong><br />
Development Administration at the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>.<br />
This 2000 edition <strong>of</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>nus marks the beginning <strong>of</strong> a new century by appearing<br />
in a ``new look'' format. The editor and the Editorial Committee have<br />
opted for an ethnic format that is more suited to the new <strong>Africa</strong>n Renaissance<br />
approach being adopted by our country.<br />
Erratum<br />
Figure 1 on page 52 <strong>of</strong> the previous edition should read:<br />
Figure 1: A version <strong>of</strong> the Toulmin-Dunn model for policy arguments<br />
Given<br />
GROUNDS<br />
(policy-relevant<br />
information)<br />
~<br />
CONCLUSION<br />
(policy proposal/<br />
claim)<br />
"<br />
Therefore<br />
(inference)<br />
QUALIFIER<br />
(Modulates strength<br />
<strong>of</strong> the conclusion)<br />
And Since<br />
WARRANT<br />
(justification for<br />
the inference)<br />
Unless<br />
REBUTTAL<br />
~ ~<br />
Because<br />
BACKING<br />
Because<br />
BACKING<br />
7
Informal collection:<br />
a matter <strong>of</strong> survival amongst<br />
the urban vulnerable<br />
Michelle McLean<br />
Keywords: informal collectors; integrated waste management; poverty; recyclables;<br />
residential areas<br />
ABSTRACT<br />
In the last two or three years, informal collectors have become frequent<br />
visitors to residential areas surrounding central Durban. Twenty <strong>of</strong> these<br />
collectors (15 males and 5 females) were interviewed in the Glenwood-Berea<br />
residential area, a few kilometres from the central business district. All but<br />
one collector supported dependants, most <strong>of</strong> whom lived at the permanent<br />
homes <strong>of</strong> collectors, which were generally in rural areas. Collectors originally<br />
came to Durban in search <strong>of</strong> employment, which was not forthcoming. As a<br />
result, they have resorted to collecting cardboard and, to a lesser extent,<br />
other recyclables, to generate an income. Several collectors had moved into<br />
the residential area because <strong>of</strong> the large number <strong>of</strong> informal collectors operating<br />
in more commercial areas. The recent decrease in the wastepaper<br />
price severely affected the income-generating capacity <strong>of</strong> collectors. As individuals,<br />
and also considering the households supported by these collectors,<br />
many were experiencing extreme poverty.<br />
INTRODUCTION<br />
On 6 February 1998, President Nelson Mandela addressed Parliament at the<br />
penultimate sitting <strong>of</strong> the first democratic government <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Topping<br />
his list <strong>of</strong> successes was the amelioration <strong>of</strong> the conditions <strong>of</strong> the most vul-<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>nus <strong>30</strong>(2)2000 8
nerable citizens ± the poor, women, the disabled, children and the rural masses<br />
± ``the primary victims <strong>of</strong> the iniquitous system from which we have just<br />
emerged'' (Anon 1998: 5). The former President provided impressive statistics<br />
for the provision <strong>of</strong> clean and accessible water, electricity, telephones, as well<br />
as the initiation <strong>of</strong> primary school feeding schemes, land redistribution and the<br />
building <strong>of</strong> more than 500 clinics. Despite these documented successes, according<br />
to the recent Poverty and Inequality Report (1998), prepared for the<br />
Office <strong>of</strong> the Executive Deputy President and the Inter-Ministerial Committee for<br />
Poverty and Inequality (PIR 1998a and 1998b), most <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n households<br />
still experience outright poverty or are vulnerable to becoming poor (PIR<br />
1998a: 1). Moreover, the poorest 40 percent <strong>of</strong> households receive only 11<br />
percent <strong>of</strong> the total income, whilst the richest 10 percent receive over 40 percent<br />
<strong>of</strong> the total income, making <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> a country with one <strong>of</strong> the highest<br />
income inequality pr<strong>of</strong>iles. Poverty is particularly prevalent in the rural areas,<br />
where 72 percent <strong>of</strong> the ``poor'' reside (PIR 1998a: 2).<br />
Unemployment is one <strong>of</strong> the major contributors to poverty, with the current<br />
estimate for unemployment being between 25 and 40 percent (Urban Foundation<br />
1990: 9; PIR 1998a: 6).``Jobs, jobs and jobs is the clarion call that should<br />
guide us'' were President Mandela's words (Anon 1998: 8). Job creation is no<br />
doubt the solution to the alleviation <strong>of</strong> poverty, but depends on economic growth<br />
(Godsell & Buys 1992: 635). A recent Human Sciences Research Council<br />
(HSRC) media release (August 1999), however, predicts that while the labour<br />
force is expanding at a rate <strong>of</strong> about 3 percent per annum, employment growth<br />
is negative, with only one in <strong>30</strong> new entrants in the labour market likely to find<br />
formal employment (HSRC 1999a: 1). Rural areas will be particularly negatively<br />
affected (HSRC 1999a: 2). To cast further shadow on an already bleak situation,<br />
it has further been forecast that over the next four years, net job creation<br />
will be experienced only in the pr<strong>of</strong>essional and managerial categories (HSRC<br />
1999b: 1). The information technology sector is predicted to grow by 40 percent,<br />
while employment in the mining sector will decline (HSRC 1999b: 1±2).<br />
Job losses are also expected in the manufacturing sector (45 000 jobs), in the<br />
public services sector (74 000 jobs) and in the unskilled labour force. Artisans<br />
can expect only a 10 percent increase in demand for their skills in the 1998±<br />
2003 period (HSRC 1999b: 1±2). COSATU has estimated (confirmed by analysts)<br />
that at least 500 000 jobs have already been lost over the past four years<br />
(Sunday Tribune, 18 July 1999: 4), a trend that is likely to continue in the short<br />
to medium term.<br />
9
Thus, despite the Government's Reconstruction and Development (RDP) and<br />
Growth, Employment and Reconstruction (GEAR) Programmes, and the promise<br />
<strong>of</strong> a better quality <strong>of</strong> life for all <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>ns, the economy has failed to<br />
recover sufficiently to make inroads into the high level <strong>of</strong> unemployment. The<br />
net result over the past few years has been an increasing informal sector,<br />
un<strong>of</strong>ficially estimated to account for 10±40 percent <strong>of</strong> the labour force (Huntley<br />
et al 1989: 72±73; Roux 1991: 103). From the 1997 October Household Survey,<br />
it would appear that 1.8 million individuals generate an income from the<br />
informal sector (CSS 1998: 59), with <strong>Africa</strong>ns accounting for 86 percent <strong>of</strong> the<br />
self-employed (PIR 1998b: 79). Most individuals in this sector are involved in<br />
survivalist activities and therefore represent a severely disadvantaged and<br />
vulnerable group in the labour market (PIR 1998b: 79). Informal employment<br />
would include activities by shopkeepers, street sellers, artisans, shebeen operators,<br />
and <strong>of</strong> relevance to this study, informal collectors. Based on two basic<br />
poverty lines, the Supplemental Living Level (SLL) and the Minimum Living<br />
Level (MLL) (PSLSD 1994), it is estimated that 45 percent <strong>of</strong> the self-employed<br />
earn below the poverty line, with only informal store-keepers generally earning<br />
above this level (PIR 1998b: 80±81). Poverty is, however, not a static condition.<br />
While some individuals, households and communities may be permanently<br />
poor, others may oscillate above and below the poverty line (PIR 1998b: 5).<br />
These individuals and groups may thus be vulnerable, depending on the prevailing<br />
economic, social, environmental and political conditions (PIR 1998b: 5).<br />
Vulnerability therefore implies that an individual, a household or a community is<br />
at risk, being unable to plan for or cope in times <strong>of</strong> crisis. Vulnerability is also<br />
characterised by a lack <strong>of</strong> assets or the inability to accumulate different assets,<br />
thereby increasing the risk <strong>of</strong> and predisposition to poverty (PIR 1998b: 5).<br />
The present study concentrates on the informal collectors in the Durban Metropolitan<br />
Area (DMA). As one <strong>of</strong> the poorest sectors <strong>of</strong> the urban poor, they<br />
appear powerless to regulate the level <strong>of</strong> their income, which is dependent on,<br />
amongst other factors, the price and availability <strong>of</strong> recyclable commodities.<br />
Without any assets, it is unlikely that they (or their families) would cope with a<br />
crisis (eg the recent cardboard price decrease). For many years, informal collectors<br />
have operated in the central business district <strong>of</strong> the city, generating an<br />
income from hawking cardboard and newspaper. In the central Durban area,<br />
over 200 informal female collectors currently operate under the auspices <strong>of</strong> the<br />
Self-Employed Women's Union (SEWU) (DSW 1998: 3). More recently (2±3<br />
10
years), collectors have become a common sight (and even residents) in residential<br />
areas just outside central Durban, particularly those areas close to<br />
shopping centres, which provide a continuous source <strong>of</strong> cardboard. Early in the<br />
morning, <strong>of</strong>ten before first light, collectors rummage through the domestic refuse<br />
bags left overnight outside residential properties. Either by means <strong>of</strong> a<br />
trolley (usually from a supermarket), or by carrying their commodities on their<br />
head, collectors transport their goods to the nearest agent, several kilometres<br />
away. The present study investigates the activities <strong>of</strong> these informal collectors<br />
in the residential areas <strong>of</strong> Glenwood/Berea in terms <strong>of</strong> the effect <strong>of</strong> the economy<br />
on their poverty status and their contributions to the waste management <strong>of</strong> the<br />
city.<br />
METHODOLOGY<br />
Study area<br />
Based on a personal observation <strong>of</strong> the appearance and subsequent increase<br />
<strong>of</strong> informal collectors in the residential area <strong>of</strong> Glenwood/Berea, 4±5 km from<br />
central Durban, this study was undertaken to gather information with regard to<br />
these collectors and their activities. The study area <strong>of</strong> Glenwood/Berea incorporates<br />
two shopping centres (Davenport and Berea). Collection agents, to<br />
whom the collectors sell their commodities, are located a few kilometres to the<br />
south <strong>of</strong> Glenwood, in the Sydney/Williams Road area (Congella), and include a<br />
buyback centre (McLean 1998: 257) and paper and scrap metal merchants.<br />
Questionnaire<br />
A structured questionnaire was completed during interviews with 20 informal<br />
collectors who were encountered in the area during a two-week period in October±<strong>No</strong>vember<br />
1998. Interviews were conducted in Zulu and transcribed onto<br />
a structured questionnaire. The responses were then transposed onto an<br />
equivalent questionnaire in English for the purpose <strong>of</strong> analysis.<br />
RESULTS<br />
Social pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> collectors<br />
Collectors were generally male (75%). Most were between 31 and 60 years <strong>of</strong><br />
11
age (table 1). The youngest collector was a 23-year-old single male (with six<br />
dependants), whilst the oldest was a 76-year-old married male.<br />
Table 1 Age and marital status <strong>of</strong> informal collectors<br />
GROUP AGE MARITAL STATUS<br />
Males 43.0 ‹13.60 8 single; 7 married<br />
(n = 15) (range: 23±76)<br />
Females 47.2 ‹ 10.23 3 single; 1 divorced;<br />
(n = 5) (range: 34±57) 1 widowed<br />
All collectors 44.1 ‹ 12.73 11 single; 7 married;<br />
(n = 20) (range: 23±76) 1 divorced; 1 widowed<br />
The permanent homes <strong>of</strong> collectors were generally in KwaZulu Natal (at least<br />
80%). One collector was a Zimbabwean, and another originated from the<br />
Transkei. A number <strong>of</strong> collectors returned home only when they could afford to<br />
do so (<strong>30</strong>%), while others returned home during holidays or at Christmas (35%).<br />
Most lived in Durban during the week (85%), largely in Dalton Road or Warwick<br />
Avenue, which were collection points, or where the merchants who bought<br />
collectors' commodities were located (Dalton Rd). The Warwick Avenue area is<br />
close to the fresh produce market and is a hub for bus, train and taxi transport<br />
into and out <strong>of</strong> the city. The remaining three collectors travelled into the city from<br />
surrounding townships. The majority <strong>of</strong> collectors remained in Durban over the<br />
weekend (70%), as many collected on Saturdays and Sundays.<br />
Nineteen collectors (including all the women) had dependants, who were<br />
generally living at the permanent home (80%). Sixty-four children and 19 adults<br />
were supported by 19 collectors (table 2). At the one extreme, a collector, who<br />
claimed he had been collecting for nine months only and earned an estimated<br />
R6.00/day (R168/month), supported six children and three adults. All but one<br />
collector indicated that this collection provided the sole source <strong>of</strong> income. The<br />
exception was a 76-year-old male who lived with his employed wife in the<br />
Glenwood area, and who had been collecting for two weeks only.<br />
12
Table 2 Dependants supported by collectors (n = 19)<br />
DEPENDANTS MALE FEMALE TOTAL<br />
COLLECTORS COLLECTORS COLLECTORS<br />
(n = 14) (n =5) (n = 19)<br />
Adults 16 3 19<br />
Children 45 16 61<br />
TOTAL 61 19 80<br />
Average number >4 4<br />
Collection activities: income and areas <strong>of</strong> collection<br />
Most collectors (55%) had been involved in collection activities for 1±2 years<br />
(figure 1). All intimated that they had originally come to Durban in search <strong>of</strong><br />
employment, which had not been forthcoming.<br />
Figure 1 Months or years spent in informal collection activities<br />
Months/years <strong>of</strong> collection<br />
5yr<br />
>2yr<br />
Male<br />
Female<br />
2yr<br />
1yr<br />
7 mo±1 yr<br />
0±6 mo<br />
0 2 4 6 8 10<br />
Number <strong>of</strong> collectors (n = 20)<br />
13
Collectors estimated that they earned R6±R<strong>30</strong> per day, with 45 percent earning<br />
R6±R10 per day and <strong>30</strong> percent earning R16±R20 per day. Four collectors (one<br />
female) earned R<strong>30</strong> per day. If the estimated income is calculated as a monthly<br />
income, based on the number <strong>of</strong> days worked by each collector, more realistic<br />
figures for income are obtained (figure 2). A male collector, who worked seven<br />
days a week earned R840 from collecting four recyclable commodities (cardboard,<br />
newspaper, other paper and scrap metal).<br />
Figure 2 Estimated monthly earnings <strong>of</strong> informal collectors, based on<br />
their income per day and the number <strong>of</strong> days worked<br />
Estimated earnings per month<br />
Earnings per month (rands)<br />
801±900<br />
701±800<br />
601±700<br />
501±600<br />
401±500<br />
<strong>30</strong>1±400<br />
201±<strong>30</strong>0<br />
101±200<br />
Male<br />
Female<br />
1±100<br />
0 1 2 3 4 5 6<br />
Number <strong>of</strong> collectors (n = 20)<br />
For seven (35%) collectors, Glenwood was their first collection area; they had<br />
not collected elsewhere. Two <strong>of</strong> the 13 collectors who had collected in another<br />
area (mainly in the Warwick Triangle or city centre), prior to moving into<br />
Glenwood, no longer collected in those areas because, in their opinion, there<br />
were too many collectors. In Glenwood/Berea, most collectors spent either five<br />
(weekdays), six or seven days collecting; those collectors spent less time in<br />
their second area <strong>of</strong> collection, where they had collected prior to moving to the<br />
14
esidential area. Twelve collectors (60%), including the five women, still collected<br />
elsewhere, with at least 55 percent operating in both areas each day. On<br />
the whole, it would appear that women spent more time collecting in two areas.<br />
Reasons for collection/non-collection on particular days ranged from going<br />
home on weekends (25%), that there was plenty to collect on those days (15%),<br />
or conversely, that there was not much to collect on the other days (10%).<br />
Others visited friends (one collector), went to church on Sunday (one collector)<br />
or claimed that the store from which he collected was closed on a Sunday (one<br />
collector). Almost one-third <strong>of</strong> collectors (<strong>30</strong>%) collected material from residences,<br />
while at least eight (40%) collected from the Berea or Davenport<br />
shopping centre. Others (25%) collected from smaller shops in the area.<br />
The number <strong>of</strong> days worked had an impact on the income generated (table 3).<br />
Working for more than two days markedly increased a collector's earnings,<br />
although there was little difference between working three or five days, or six or<br />
seven days. Factors that will have influenced the income generated would<br />
include owning a trolley, recyclables collected, and whether collectors operated<br />
in one or two areas.<br />
Table 3 Average earnings per month in relation to the number <strong>of</strong> days<br />
spent on collection<br />
Number <strong>of</strong> days<br />
collecting<br />
Monthly income based<br />
on number <strong>of</strong> days worked<br />
2 (10% <strong>of</strong> collectors) R120 ‹ 56.67<br />
3 (5%) R360<br />
5 (<strong>30</strong>%) R360 ‹ 160.00<br />
6 (20%) R420 ‹ 229.78<br />
7 (35%) R432.00 ‹ 266.54<br />
Owning a trolley affected a collector's activities (table 4). Trolley-owners earned<br />
more despite working fewer days, and needed to operate in one area only.<br />
Presumably, a trolley would increase the speed at which cardboard could be<br />
collected and transported to the agent, forcing those without trolleys to spend<br />
more time collecting and to move to another area in order to obtain material. In<br />
the present study, only one woman and eight men had access to a trolley. Most<br />
<strong>of</strong> those not owning a trolley indicated that they carried their merchandise on<br />
15
their head. Three women sold their cardboard or paper to an agent with a motor<br />
vehicle who called on them on a daily basis in the Warwick Triangle. These<br />
women would therefore have to transport some <strong>of</strong> their recyclables to the<br />
market area, several kilometres from Glenwood. Interestingly, while two males<br />
also collected in the market area and four others in the CBD, none used the<br />
same pick-up facilities indicated by the women. Instead, they chose to take their<br />
goods to one <strong>of</strong> the Congella agents. Three <strong>of</strong> these males owned trolleys, and<br />
another borrowed one. Similarly, the single female collector who owned a<br />
trolley, and who also collected in the Warwick Avenue area, where the pick-up<br />
service existed, chose to sell her commodities in Congella. The agent who runs<br />
the small buyback centre in Williams Road, to whom most collectors sold their<br />
cardboard at the time <strong>of</strong> the interviews, said that he was paying 8±10c more per<br />
kilogram than other agents. This higher price was sufficient to warrant collectors<br />
travelling the extra distance to hawk their cardboard. At least seventeen collectors<br />
(85%) traded their commodities in Congella.<br />
Table 4 Comparison <strong>of</strong> earnings, number <strong>of</strong> days spent collecting and<br />
recyclable items recovered by collectors with and without access<br />
to trolleys<br />
Collectors Days per week Areas <strong>of</strong> collection* Monthly<br />
(n = 20) collecting (maximum = 2) earnings<br />
With trolleys 4.89 ‹ 2.03 67% in 1 area R371.11 ‹ 275.52<br />
(n =9)<br />
Without trolleys 6.0 ‹ 1.0 73% in 2 areas R342 ‹ 176.94<br />
(n = 11)<br />
*Glenwood/Berea + elsewhere<br />
Materials collected<br />
Of a possible seven recyclable items that could be recovered (cardboard,<br />
newspaper, other paper, cans, glass, plastic, scrap metal), the highest number<br />
collected was four (table 5). All collected cardboard, with fewer than half collecting<br />
other forms <strong>of</strong> paper (figure 3). Seven (35%) collected only cardboard.<br />
The women generally collected all forms <strong>of</strong> paper, with none collecting any<br />
other commodity. Scrap metal was the next most frequently collected (6 males)<br />
commodity, followed by cans. Five scrap metal collectors owned trolleys, which<br />
obviously facilitated transport to the merchants in Congella. When asked where<br />
16
the metal was obtained, one collector indicated the landfill site, two answered<br />
``anywhere'' and two did not respond. Scrap metal, despite a low price per<br />
kilogram, is a valuable commodity because <strong>of</strong> its mass. It is not uncommon to<br />
see a collector pushing a trolley loaded with old car exhausts, refrigerator doors,<br />
other car parts, or even old lead plumbing pipes to a scrap metal merchant. Of<br />
particular concern, however, is the continued and rapid disappearance <strong>of</strong> items<br />
such as steel manhole covers and bridge railings, presumably removed for their<br />
worth as scrap metal. Aluminium in particular is highly valued, with some<br />
dealers paying up to R3.00/kilogram. At this stage, the perpetrators responsible<br />
for dismantling public structures have not been identified, as much <strong>of</strong> this activity<br />
takes place at night. It is probable, although there is no evidence forthcoming,<br />
that some informal collectors may be involved in such activities. If this<br />
is indeed the case, the blame lies not with the collectors per se, as many barely<br />
exist above the poverty line, but with the unscrupulous scrap metal dealers who<br />
indirectly encourage theft by purchasing the merchandise, fully aware <strong>of</strong> the<br />
origins.<br />
Table 5 Earnings per day, in relation to the number <strong>of</strong> recyclable items<br />
collected<br />
Recyclable items Male: female Number with Earnings per day<br />
(maximum = 7)<br />
trolleys<br />
1 5:2 2 R12.71 ‹ 6.99<br />
2 6:0 5 R16.67 ‹ 8.16<br />
3 2:3 1 R20.00 ‹ 10.00<br />
4 2:0 1 R18.50 ‹ 16.<strong>30</strong><br />
<strong>No</strong>t a single collector recovered plastic or glass. Initially, the buyback centre in<br />
Williams Road, where collectors hawked their cardboard, also bought plastic,<br />
cans and glass. Poor support by collectors for these commodities and difficulties<br />
experienced by the owner in disposing <strong>of</strong> them had forced him to collect only<br />
paper products. Collectors gave three main reasons for not hawking particular<br />
items: the selling price was not sufficiently high (50%); the commodities were<br />
scarce (<strong>30</strong>%); or they were unaware that these materials could be traded (15%).<br />
A comparison was made between the income generated per day and the<br />
number <strong>of</strong> recyclable items collected (table 5). Those collecting cardboard only<br />
earned considerably less than those collecting at least two commodities (mainly<br />
newspaper or other paper or scrap metal).<br />
17
Figure 3 Number <strong>of</strong> collectors recovering recyclable items.<br />
Recyclables collected<br />
Plastic<br />
Scrap metal<br />
Male<br />
Female<br />
Glass<br />
Cans<br />
Other paper<br />
Newspaper<br />
Cardboard<br />
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20<br />
Number <strong>of</strong> collectors (n = 20)<br />
Sixteen (80%) collectors removed food from domestic refuse bags. When<br />
asked if collection would be facilitated if ``valuable'' goods were separated from<br />
the general waste by home-owners or storekeepers, two collectors indicated<br />
that this was already done by storekeepers. The other collectors agreed that<br />
this would save time. In general, it would appear that cardboard, because <strong>of</strong> its<br />
bulk, is separated from the main domestic waste, and that in rummaging<br />
through bags, collectors search for food and other ``valuable'' items (eg clothing,<br />
household goods). In response to whether they minded searching through<br />
someone else's waste, none <strong>of</strong> the collectors objected. Seventeen (85%)<br />
clarified their response by saying that money was important or that if one<br />
minded, one would not get money. From such responses, which were not<br />
probed further by the interviewer, it is difficult to gauge whether collectors in fact<br />
did not mind, or whether they had no choice. For two collectors, this was a way<br />
<strong>of</strong> life, and one collector admitted to enjoying it.<br />
Difficulties experienced by collectors<br />
It would appear that the collectors' market is competitive. When asked about<br />
who was entitled to commodities in an area (ie, did collectors operate within<br />
18
territories?), eighteen (90%) indicated that collecting was done on a ``first-comefirst-served''<br />
basis. The remaining collectors had an understanding with a<br />
storekeeper, who kept the goods aside for them. All but one collector indicated<br />
that his or her goods had been stolen, and on all occasions the culprit had been<br />
another collector. The response <strong>of</strong> most collectors that an organisation <strong>of</strong> informal<br />
collectors would be beneficial is difficult to reconcile in view <strong>of</strong> the fact<br />
that they cannot trust each other with their belongings. Three collectors believed<br />
that such an association would give them voice, which would ultimately<br />
be advantageous to all collectors. The benefits <strong>of</strong> belonging to an organisation<br />
became clear when SEWU recently secured accommodation for many <strong>of</strong> the<br />
female street traders in Durban (Lund & Skinner 1998: 21). At least 200 female<br />
informal collectors in the CBD already operate under the auspices <strong>of</strong> SEWU<br />
(DSW 1998: 3).<br />
Only one collector had been chased by a property-owner. This would suggest<br />
that informal collectors may not be viewed negatively by property- or shopowners.<br />
In response to the possibility <strong>of</strong> establishing an informal association,<br />
collectors felt that recognition by property-owners would facilitate and promote<br />
their activities, resulting in a better return for their labour-intensive activities.<br />
Recognition by property-owners would allow them relatively unrestricted but<br />
presumably controlled access to materials. Of more importance in the long<br />
term, however, would be recognition by local councils and government. A<br />
number <strong>of</strong> collectors (55%) believed that this recognition might result in some<br />
form <strong>of</strong> assistance or sponsorship, such as the provision <strong>of</strong> a trolley. Implicit in<br />
the collectors' desire to be recognised by local authorities lies their belief <strong>of</strong> the<br />
value associated with the work they undertake (eg cleaning). Most collectors did<br />
not understand the true environmental benefits or impact <strong>of</strong> their activities. Only<br />
three collectors (two women) understood that ``recycling'' meant reuse <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />
For most, it was a means to get an income. There is no doubt that collectors<br />
divert several hundred tonnes <strong>of</strong> recyclable paper products from the landfill site.<br />
A single buyback centre in the Warwick Triangle turns over several tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />
cardboard per week (David Cooper, Coopak Recycling, personal communication),<br />
while the buyback centre in Williams Road may purchase in excess <strong>of</strong> 100<br />
tonnes per month from informal hawkers (Jeremy Droyman, Don't Waste<br />
Services, personal communication).<br />
The problems highlighted by collectors were few, but were <strong>of</strong> a serious nature:<br />
theft, accommodation and transport. One collector believed that the local authority<br />
should provide accommodation, while several others felt that trolleys<br />
19
would facilitate their work. Collectors (45%) requested additional buyback<br />
centres, possibly reflecting the long distances they have to travel to sell their<br />
merchandise. Others believed that centres needed to increase prices. At the<br />
time <strong>of</strong> the study, the highest price paid for cardboard was 24c/kg, but the<br />
average price was 15c/kg. If, as some collectors indicated, they earned R<strong>30</strong> per<br />
day, then they were collecting 150 kg <strong>of</strong> cardboard per day.<br />
DISCUSSION<br />
The increase in the number <strong>of</strong> informal collectors and their recent appearance<br />
in residential areas reflect the difficult economic climate. The prospect <strong>of</strong> finding<br />
employment or generating an income in the city will continue to attract people<br />
from impoverished rural and semirural areas, exacerbating the socioeconomic<br />
situation facing city planners. Many flocking to the city have little or no education,<br />
many cannot speak English, and most do not have any skills to <strong>of</strong>fer a<br />
potential employer. Since the commercial sector is facing the same economic<br />
constraints as the agricultural sector, retrenching rather than employing, the net<br />
result is that many migrating to urban areas cannot find formal employment and<br />
are forced into the informal sector. Without appropriate skills or finance to start<br />
informal businesses, many have to resort to collecting recyclables to generate<br />
some form <strong>of</strong> income.<br />
Vulnerability to extreme poverty<br />
Most informal collectors have no visible assets, except a trolley and the clothes<br />
they wear (<strong>of</strong>ten in poor condition). At the time <strong>of</strong> the interviews, the R20 per<br />
day (based on 15c/kg for cardboard) earned from 8 to 12 hours <strong>of</strong> labour would<br />
barely have covered the costs <strong>of</strong> accommodation and food, let alone support a<br />
family. Many collectors do not have any formal accommodation, <strong>of</strong>ten sleeping<br />
in makeshift shelters. Salvaging food and other usable valuables from domestic<br />
refuse is therefore a survival strategy for most collectors. In the light <strong>of</strong> the<br />
international ``rule <strong>of</strong> thumb'' measure that absolute poverty is defined as existing<br />
on US $1 per day (R6/day) (Klasen 1997: 54), most collectors met this<br />
minimum requirement. In real terms, however, even if this sum should meet the<br />
daily subsistence requirements <strong>of</strong> individual collectors, it is unlikely to even<br />
approximate the income necessary to support the families <strong>of</strong> these collectors.<br />
There is a further consideration. These income calculations are based on a<br />
cardboard price <strong>of</strong> 15c/kg. Recently (April/May 1999), because <strong>of</strong> an oversupply<br />
<strong>of</strong> material, the price decreased by 5c/kg. For many, this may seem incon-<br />
20
sequential, but for collectors it will have had important consequences on their<br />
poverty status and the wellbeing <strong>of</strong> their families (figures 4 and 5). If we calculate<br />
the earnings <strong>of</strong> collectors, based on 15c/kg (1998) and 10c/kg (1999),<br />
using two poverty indices (RDP (1995) for households and PSLSD (1994) for<br />
individuals), the vulnerability <strong>of</strong> these individuals and their families to absolute<br />
poverty is highlighted (figures 4 and 5). The activities <strong>of</strong> these informal collectors<br />
are therefore survivalist in nature, with the level <strong>of</strong> subsistence highly dependent<br />
on market trends.<br />
Figure 4 The effect <strong>of</strong> a recent cardboard price decrease on the poverty<br />
status <strong>of</strong> individual collectors (PSLSD (1994) calculations)<br />
Individual poverty levels<br />
Number <strong>of</strong> collectors (n = 20)<br />
10<br />
8<br />
6<br />
4<br />
2<br />
0<br />
Male<br />
8<br />
Female<br />
3 3<br />
2<br />
15c/kg<br />
10c/kg<br />
Price <strong>of</strong> cardboard<br />
Cartboard collection: a labour-intensive and competitive market<br />
The collection <strong>of</strong> recyclables is labour-intensive, with many collectors having to<br />
work seven days a week. With so many informal collectors, the market has<br />
become competitive, as collectors in the present study intimated, many having<br />
had cardboard stolen by another collector. As a result, some have been forced<br />
to operate in two areas on a daily basis, the areas <strong>of</strong>ten being several kilometres<br />
apart. Residential areas may thus have become a refuge, providing a<br />
source <strong>of</strong> `valuables' that may not have been available in the city (eg clothing).<br />
Trolley-owners, however, are able to concentrate their activities in one area.<br />
Those without trolleys are forced to move between two collection areas, wasting<br />
valuable time. The lack <strong>of</strong> trolleys also restricts the volume <strong>of</strong> merchandise that<br />
can be collected and carried, inevitably reducing the collectors' income.<br />
21
Figure 5 The effect <strong>of</strong> a recent cardboard price decrease on the poverty<br />
status <strong>of</strong> collectors' households (RDP (1995) calculations)<br />
Household poverty levels<br />
Number <strong>of</strong> collectors with<br />
dependants (n = 19)<br />
10<br />
9<br />
8<br />
7<br />
6<br />
5<br />
4<br />
3<br />
2<br />
1<br />
0<br />
9<br />
Poor<br />
Ultra-poor<br />
6<br />
5 5<br />
15c/kg<br />
10c/kg<br />
Price <strong>of</strong> cardboard<br />
Age may be an important consideration in a competitive market. The average<br />
age <strong>of</strong> the collectors in this study was 45 years. In another study (October/<br />
<strong>No</strong>vember 1998) on the pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> informal collectors visiting a newly established<br />
multimaterial buyback centre in the city centre (McLean 1998: 258), most collectors<br />
were <strong>30</strong>±39 years old, and had become informal hawkers because<br />
formal employment had not been forthcoming. These younger individuals would<br />
be able to collect and transport greater quantities <strong>of</strong> paper and cardboard,<br />
which may have curtailed the collecting activities <strong>of</strong> older collectors, forcing<br />
them to seek new domains further afield (eg residential areas).<br />
Switching collectable commodities: an option?<br />
Cardboard and paper have been collected by informal hawkers for many years.<br />
It has, however, become apparent that with the increase in individuals resorting<br />
to collection as a means <strong>of</strong> survival, the market has become extremely competitive.<br />
In 1998, Mondi Recycling paid out R9 million to small business and<br />
hawkers (approximately 5 000 individuals), with the tonnage <strong>of</strong> wastepaper<br />
from this segment <strong>of</strong> the market having increased by 190 percent over the past<br />
22
five years (Anon 1999: 35). Despite this competition and contrary to expectations,<br />
the present survey revealed that few had switched to other potential<br />
income-generating commodities (eg glass, cans, plastic). Many collectors interviewed<br />
appeared unaware that these commodities could be traded, while<br />
those who knew, regarded these items as scarce, or thought that the prices<br />
paid were too low. The recent wastepaper price decrease may cause some<br />
collectors to reconsider their options. This would, however, depend on the<br />
existence <strong>of</strong> an appropriate infrastructure for hawking these commodities. The<br />
informal cardboard or paper market infrastructure is well established. The recent<br />
concept <strong>of</strong> small buyback centres, effectively bringing the paper recyclers<br />
to the hawkers, has met with great success (McLean 1998: 257; Anon<br />
1999: 35). The same does not, however, apply to all recyclable commodities.<br />
Of the other possible recyclables, cans may be a viable alternative for collectors.<br />
Although Collect-a-Can, the registered beverage can collector, was established<br />
only in 1993, it already boasts a 62 percent national can recovery<br />
average (Kock 1999: 40). This non-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation claims to have successfully<br />
provided an income for at least 20 000 hawkers and small business<br />
entrepreneurs (largely in Gauteng) by providing a user-friendly infrastructure<br />
(Kock 1999: 40). KwaZulu-Natal does not match this national average, and so<br />
considerable opportunities exist in this province for collectors to include cans<br />
amongst their saleable commodities. A walk around shopping centres and<br />
corner cafe s would give one an indication <strong>of</strong> the potential volume <strong>of</strong> cans that<br />
can be recovered from the waste stream. Until recently, when the wastepaper<br />
price dropped substantially, the prices paid for cans (6±10c/kg) was almost half<br />
that <strong>of</strong> cardboard. Prices are currently similar, which might entice collectors to<br />
switch to a less exploited commodity. Can collection may, however, pose a<br />
problem for collectors without transport. Cardboard can be neatly folded and<br />
many kilograms can be carried to the agent on one's head. Cans would be<br />
difficult to transport without a trolley or a bag, and most informal collectors do<br />
not have these.<br />
Considering the difficulties experienced in glass recycling over the past year, it<br />
is not surprising that informal collectors have not considered glass a collectible<br />
item. A recent communication (September 1999) from the Glass Recycling<br />
Association is encouraging, with the infrastructure for glass recycling set to<br />
become more user-friendly (Dick Poultney, Glass Recycling Association, personal<br />
communication). However, marketing campaigns will be needed, prices<br />
23
will have to be reviewed and the agents will have to become more accessible to<br />
collectors before informal collectors will recognise the merit <strong>of</strong> recovering glass.<br />
For informal collectors, plastic recycling is also fraught with logistical difficulties,<br />
making it <strong>of</strong> little value as a potential source <strong>of</strong> income. Plastic is bulky and lightweight<br />
and large volumes need to be sold to make it worthwhile. In addition,<br />
formal plastic collectors and recyclers generally require certain types <strong>of</strong> plastic<br />
only, which, for the average person, are not easily distinguishable. The value<br />
associated with the various plastic types is also dependent on the volumes <strong>of</strong><br />
used plastic available, <strong>of</strong>ten resulting in a market surplus. For collectors,<br />
earning a sustainable income from collecting these commodities is therefore not<br />
viable at present. Market prices need to be stabilised and agents appointed who<br />
will guarantee a permanent market.<br />
Other solutions<br />
There is no doubt that informal collectors are responsible for diverting several<br />
thousand tonnes <strong>of</strong> cardboard and paper from the waste stream, and with the<br />
appropriate infrastructure, other recyclables could be included. Because <strong>of</strong> the<br />
current and predicted continued high levels <strong>of</strong> unemployment, the number <strong>of</strong><br />
individuals seeking an income will increase further, with many being absorbed<br />
into the informal sector. The incidence <strong>of</strong> informal collectors in the city and<br />
residential areas is therefore likely to increase. Local councils need to take<br />
cognisance <strong>of</strong> the environmental and economic impact <strong>of</strong> the activities <strong>of</strong> these<br />
individuals, which are largely tw<strong>of</strong>old: reduced spending on labour for street<br />
litter control, thereby enhancing the overall appearance <strong>of</strong> the city, and reducing<br />
the impact on landfills. Many collectors have requested formal recognition,<br />
which they feel would facilitate their work. Local authorities and recycling industries<br />
should therefore take the initiative to support collectors (eg by providing<br />
trolleys and identifiable clothing); to upgrade the infrastructure for can, glass<br />
and even plastic recycling; to educate collectors in this regard; and to provide<br />
additional, more accessible buyback centres.<br />
It may even be possible to incorporate informal collectors into the wastemanagement<br />
systems operating in residential and commercial areas. To this<br />
end, householders and factories could separate recyclables for collectors,<br />
which would include consumable food items, upon which many rely for subsistence.<br />
Based on the preliminary results <strong>of</strong> a survey <strong>of</strong> Durban businesses,<br />
considerable informal recycling already occurs in the industrial sector (Karen<br />
24
Thomas, DSW, personal communication). If these industry±informal collector<br />
associations could be recognised, encouraged and even legitimised, there<br />
would be environmental, social and economic benefits for all parties.<br />
FINAL COMMENTS<br />
Often, with no other source <strong>of</strong> income, informal collectors (and their dependants)<br />
rely on both domestic and commercial ``waste'' for survival. Since<br />
much <strong>of</strong> this waste is reusable or recyclable, and since it is unlikely that the<br />
economy will recover sufficiently to improve the quality <strong>of</strong> life for these individuals<br />
and their families, collectors should be incorporated into the waste<br />
management <strong>of</strong> the city. Local councils should recognise the potential social<br />
and environmental implications <strong>of</strong> facilitating informal collection. There are<br />
those who believe that one <strong>of</strong> the most revealing environmental audits <strong>of</strong> a city<br />
is how efficiently its inhabitants and commercial sector make use <strong>of</strong> the city's<br />
resources, and how, in what form and on what scale the wastes are generated,<br />
reused, recycled, treated or disposed (Hardoy et al 1995: 132). Durban faces<br />
problems with a growing informal sector that needs to be accommodated and<br />
landfills that are reaching capacity. The challenge which faces local councils is<br />
therefore to manage these problems effectively, concurrently and sustainably.<br />
BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />
Anon 1998. The building has begun! Government's report `98 to the nation. Pretoria:<br />
Government Communication and Information System.<br />
Anon 1999. Wastepaper recycling opens up opportunities for small business. Resource<br />
1(1):35.<br />
Central Statistical Services (CSS) 1998. Employment and unemployment in <strong>South</strong><br />
<strong>Africa</strong>: October Household Survey 1994±1997. Pretoria: Central Statistical Services.<br />
(Statistical Release PO317.10.)<br />
Durban Solid Waste (DSW) 1998. Report on Durban solid waste: Waste Minimisation<br />
Office activities, 15 December 1998.<br />
Godsell, B & Buys, J 1992. Growth and poverty: towards some shared goals, in Wealth<br />
or poverty? Critical choices for <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, edited by R Schire. Cape Town:<br />
Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press:635±656.<br />
Hardoy, J E, Mitlin, D & Satterthwaite, D 1995. Environmental problems in Third World<br />
cities. London: Earthscan.<br />
Human Sciences Research Council (HSRC) 1999a. Media release: Unemployed eager<br />
to take any job: HSRC study. http://www.hsrc.ac.za<br />
Human Sciences Research Council (HSRC) 1999b. Media release: Employment forecasts<br />
till 2003: HSRC study. http://www.hsrc.ac.za<br />
25
Huntley, B, Siegried, R & Sunter, C 1989. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n environments into the twentyfirst<br />
century. Cape Town: Human & Rousseau.<br />
Klasen, S 1997. Poverty, inequality and deprivation in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>: an analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />
1993 SALDRU survey. Social Indicators Research 41:51±94.<br />
Kock, N A 1999. Recovery <strong>of</strong> beverage cans in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the R'99<br />
Congress, vol III, Geneva, February 1999:36±41.<br />
Lund, F & Skinner, C 1998. Women traders in Durban: life on the streets. Indicator SA<br />
15:17±24.<br />
McLean, M 1998. Creating employment opportunities through buyback centres: a pilot<br />
study in central Durban. Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the Fourteenth Wastecon Congress,<br />
Kempton Park, October 1998, pp 257±268.<br />
Poverty and Inequality Report (PIR) 1998a. Executive summary, in Poverty and inequality<br />
in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, edited by J D May. Durban: Praxis.<br />
Poverty and Inequality Report (PIR) 1998b. Poverty and inequality in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, edited<br />
by J D May. Durban: Praxis.<br />
Project for Statistics on Living Standards and Development (PSLSD) 1994. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>ns:<br />
rich and poor: baseline household statistics. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n Labour and<br />
Development Research Unit, <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Cape Town.<br />
Research and Development Programme (RDP) 1995. Key indicators in poverty. Pretoria.<br />
Roux, A 1991. Options for employment opportunities, in Redistribution: how can it work<br />
in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>?, edited by P Moll, N Nattrass & L Loots. Cape Town: David Philip.<br />
Urban Foundation 1990. Urban debate 2010, part 2: Policy overview: the urban challenge.<br />
Johannesburg: Urban Foundation.<br />
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS<br />
The author would like to acknowledge the Foundation for Research and Development for<br />
financial support. The interviews were undertaken by Mr Emmanuel Cele, a third-year<br />
Environmental Health student, Natal Technikon. Mr Cele was the 1998 recipient <strong>of</strong> the<br />
KwaZulu-Natal Waste Minimisation, Reuse and Recycling Forum student bursary.<br />
26
The role <strong>of</strong> metropolitan<br />
government in the development<br />
process<br />
David Mmakola<br />
ABSTRACT<br />
This article explores options that could be considered in structuring a metropolitan<br />
form <strong>of</strong> local government in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, and the contribution that<br />
metropolitan local government could make in the development process. It<br />
traces the origins <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government in developing countries, using<br />
Asia as an illustration, and it maintains that the uniqueness <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>'s<br />
political economy, reflected for instance in a particular type <strong>of</strong> spatial framework,<br />
opens a wider scope for a metropolitan form <strong>of</strong> local government.<br />
Some <strong>of</strong> the key functions typically performed by metropolitan local government<br />
are indicated: economic development, strategic land use, coordination<br />
and integration. The options that could be considered in<br />
structuring a metropolitan form <strong>of</strong> government are identified and evaluated<br />
against a defined set <strong>of</strong> criteria. These options are grouped into moderate<br />
and far-reaching ones; the article argues that moderate options, when<br />
measured against the criteria, would fall short <strong>of</strong> unleashing a sustained<br />
process <strong>of</strong> development in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Finally, the key requirements are<br />
outlined for a metropolitan form <strong>of</strong> local government that could be considered<br />
for the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n situation.<br />
1 INTRODUCTION<br />
One <strong>of</strong> the essential features <strong>of</strong> the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n system <strong>of</strong> local government is<br />
the idea <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government. The Local Government Transition Act <strong>of</strong><br />
27 <strong>Africa</strong>nus <strong>30</strong>(2)2000
1993 ± as did the 1993 and 1996 constitutions, the 1998 Local Government<br />
White Paper, the Local Government Municipal Demarcation Act, and the Local<br />
Government Municipal Structures Act ± made room for higher local government<br />
structures, below which several structures fell. The argument on the role <strong>of</strong><br />
metropolitan government resurfaced in 1999, when the redemarcation <strong>of</strong> local<br />
authorities began in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. With a recognisably higher emotional content,<br />
intense debates on the workings <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government have ensued.<br />
These debates have focused on the rationale for a metropolitan government,<br />
the divisions <strong>of</strong> powers between metropolitan governments and primary structures,<br />
criteria to be used in deciding whether an area should be governed in a<br />
metropolitan arrangement or not, and other related matters <strong>of</strong> concern.<br />
The workability <strong>of</strong> a metropolitan system <strong>of</strong> local government remains a challenge<br />
<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> will have to confront now and in the not so distant future. The<br />
purpose <strong>of</strong> this paper is therefore to identify, against other countries' experiences,<br />
the determinants <strong>of</strong> a workable system <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government. The<br />
paper addresses this in four sections. The first section looks at the rationale for<br />
a metropolitan system <strong>of</strong> local government, concentrating on influences that<br />
have necessitated this form <strong>of</strong> urban governance. Secondly, the paper describes<br />
the functions <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government. Thirdly, attention is focused<br />
on the institutional options for the establishment and maintenance <strong>of</strong> metropolitan<br />
government. Finally, generic requirements for a workable system <strong>of</strong><br />
metropolitan government are considered.<br />
2 THE IDEA OF METROPOLITAN GOVERNMENT<br />
The 1993 and 1996 constitutions recognised the existence <strong>of</strong> integrated metropolitan<br />
areas in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> and the necessity for local government structures,<br />
which would take a metropolitan-wide view <strong>of</strong> local government in<br />
planning and delivering urban services. These metropolitan areas, as defined in<br />
the White Paper on Local Government (1998:58), are large urban settlements<br />
with high population densities, complex and diversified economies, and high<br />
degrees <strong>of</strong> functional integration across larger geographical areas than normal<br />
jurisdictions <strong>of</strong> municipalities. In these areas, residence and work do not necessarily<br />
coincide; the settlements have complex overlaps (Wooldridge<br />
1998:3). Use <strong>of</strong> facilities may also cut across individual municipal boundaries. In<br />
other words, there are clearly recognisable spillovers and externalities. In the<br />
absence <strong>of</strong> a metropolitan form <strong>of</strong> government, individual municipalities are<br />
28
likely to embark on irrational land-use planning and public investments, which<br />
do not take these interdependencies into account.<br />
Typically, there are problems that individual units within these larger areas are<br />
not in a position to solve on their own. In the Asian experience, the major<br />
problem that led to the assumed necessity <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government was<br />
urbanisation (Sivaramakrishnan & Green 1986:5). This problem <strong>of</strong> urbanisation<br />
confronts the majority <strong>of</strong> areas in the developing world. As the multitude <strong>of</strong><br />
complex factors pushed people to urban areas, existing local authorities became<br />
increasingly unable to cope with this in-migration. The growth <strong>of</strong> slums on<br />
the outskirts <strong>of</strong> these areas and the consequent demands for housing, water,<br />
energy, sanitation facilities and other infrastructure, made it increasingly difficult<br />
for individual local authorities to maintain a reasonable level <strong>of</strong> urban governance<br />
and service delivery. The absence <strong>of</strong> area-wide plans also gave rise to<br />
inefficient land use, as individual local authorities continued to take a narrow<br />
view <strong>of</strong> development problems facing urban areas.<br />
Alternatives other than metropolitan government structures may not be appropriate<br />
as responses to these metro-wide problems. The earliest response <strong>of</strong><br />
Asian countries was the establishment <strong>of</strong> special-purpose institutions to provide<br />
housing, water and other services individually. It became increasingly obvious<br />
that there were crosscutting institutional, financial and political issues that these<br />
organisations could not address adequately. These issues included the dominance<br />
<strong>of</strong> bureaucrats in resource allocation, rather than elected representatives,<br />
which divorced political accountability from service delivery. This<br />
situation was exacerbated by the tendency <strong>of</strong> these bodies to focus solely on<br />
the services they were providing, rather than on the relationships <strong>of</strong> these<br />
services to other services, which led to poor intersectoral coordination and lack<br />
<strong>of</strong> systematic prioritisation in service provision (Hanson 1974:9). The need for<br />
representative structures that could integrate urban planning and development<br />
became increasingly pressing, as the new structures proved wanting in integrated<br />
service delivery. This tended to make these new structures incapable<br />
<strong>of</strong> dealing with the perceived problems.<br />
Without a metropolitan form <strong>of</strong> government, economic competitiveness on the<br />
part <strong>of</strong> municipalities may be less than optimal. Globalisation has made local<br />
government key participants in economic development. Local authorities are<br />
getting more and more involved in the stimulation <strong>of</strong> the local business sector<br />
and international trade. This calls for competitiveness, so that the local authorities<br />
may benefit from international trade, for example. Metropolitan types <strong>of</strong><br />
29
local government are better placed to become competitive. When individual<br />
municipalities embark on economic development strategies, they are likely to<br />
do so without taking into account metro-wide perspectives that could harness<br />
the overall growth and development potential <strong>of</strong> the area. They may even<br />
compete against each other, defeating the purpose <strong>of</strong> local economic development.<br />
According to Wooldridge (1998:4), investors typically take a metrowide<br />
view <strong>of</strong> an area, making municipality-based investment strategies inefficient<br />
and thus less competitive.<br />
Within the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n context, racially based settlement patterns in urban<br />
areas and disparities in revenue bases necessitate metropolitan government.<br />
Local authorities derive their revenues from locally raised taxes. There is<br />
therefore the constant temptation to attract residents who can contribute more<br />
to the tax base, and exclude those who bring in less revenue (Wooldridge<br />
1998:1). Local authorities achieve this through land-use regulations that exclude<br />
undesirable or low-rateable forms <strong>of</strong> development or by imposing high<br />
entry costs that exclude poorer communities. This is complicated by the fact<br />
that urban apartheid, through racially based land-use regulations, has ensured<br />
a high coincidence between the spatial concentration <strong>of</strong> commercial tax bases<br />
and white residents. This means that individual local authorities acting in the<br />
manner described above are likely to perpetuate these inequalities, against<br />
equity goals that may be thought desirable under these circumstances. This<br />
eventually leads to the displacement, rather than the resolution <strong>of</strong> urban<br />
problems, as poorer communities are pushed to the peripheries <strong>of</strong> towns, in<br />
informal settlements, with their associated socioeconomic problems.<br />
These and many other related issues are usually considered grounds for the<br />
establishment <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government. The next section looks at the typical<br />
functions that are performed by metropolitan governments in addressing these<br />
area-wide problems.<br />
3 FUNCTIONS OF A METROPOLITAN GOVERNMENT<br />
In the light <strong>of</strong> the above, the specific functions <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government<br />
become discernible. The first function is the integration <strong>of</strong> economic, social and<br />
political dimensions in the management <strong>of</strong> a city. By being a political structure,<br />
these organisations are able to reflect local preferences and convert them into<br />
service delivery decisions, through a variety <strong>of</strong> mechanisms that may be put in<br />
<strong>30</strong>
place to generate the views <strong>of</strong> communities, such as consultative land development<br />
planning processes.<br />
The second function is the promotion <strong>of</strong> strategic land-use planning and coordinated<br />
public investment in physical and social infrastructure. Most infrastructure<br />
provision, especially the capital costs, are likely to be efficiently<br />
provided when big areas are covered, thereby capturing the undeniable<br />
economies <strong>of</strong> scale considerations. This places metropolitan authorities at<br />
strategic positions to invest in infrastructure. When these investments occur on<br />
an integrated basis, they are much more efficient. Related to the above, metropolitan<br />
governments could play cardinal roles in economic development (Sivaramakrishnan<br />
& Green 1986:28). This could promote jobs generation through<br />
sectoral investments. Metropolitan governments realise these possibilities<br />
through proper service delivery, infrastructure investments and regulatory<br />
functions that ensure targeted development. They can provide land and infrastructure,<br />
and direct business support in the form <strong>of</strong> credit, vocational training<br />
and the reviews <strong>of</strong> existing regulations. In certain instances, metropolitan<br />
governments can identify economic ills in the area, and research economic<br />
advantages and opportunities.<br />
In <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n, metropolitan government would be particularly critical in ensuring<br />
that taxes collected in functionally integrated economies are used in the<br />
whole areas, which would not be the case in the context <strong>of</strong> individual primary<br />
municipalities. As shown in the preceding section, there are disparities in the<br />
distribution <strong>of</strong> resources in the substructures within metropolitan areas. In that<br />
context the role <strong>of</strong> the metropolitan government is to collect all taxes from<br />
individual areas, which would be mainly from richer areas, and use them across<br />
the whole metropolitan area, thereby also benefiting the poor in the broader<br />
jurisdiction.<br />
In addition to the above, a metropolitan government may play many other roles.<br />
For instance, in situations <strong>of</strong> administratively weak subordinate structures<br />
metropolitan governments could perform some functions on an agency basis,<br />
until the requisite capacity had been built. It is important to note that this is a<br />
particularly acute problem in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, where many municipalities lack the<br />
administrative, managerial and financial management capabilities to run effectively.<br />
Once clarity on the functions to be performed by metropolitan governments<br />
has been achieved, the next question would be how these<br />
organisations may be structured to perform these functions. The following<br />
section is devoted to this issue.<br />
31
4 INSTITUTIONAL OPTIONS FOR THE STRUCTURING OF<br />
MUNICIPALITIES<br />
There are numerous options for the structuring <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government,<br />
each with its own strengths and weaknesses. It is important, however, for<br />
policymakers to first spell out considerations to be borne in mind before selecting<br />
a particular arrangement. It is particularly necessary to first decide on<br />
criteria for assessing the different options. Goodall (1968:82) proposes organisational<br />
simplicity, responsiveness, political acceptability and comprehensiveness<br />
as criteria to be used in deciding whether a given metropolitan<br />
structure is desirable. The following criteria may be added: the potential <strong>of</strong> a<br />
given form <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government to deal with inequities, spillovers and<br />
externalities, irrational planning and poorly directed public investment, the<br />
displacement <strong>of</strong> urban problems and reduced economic competitiveness<br />
(Wooldridge 1998:20±7).<br />
Institutional options for the structuring <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government range from<br />
moderate to far-reaching ones. The former include: annexation, the exercise <strong>of</strong><br />
extra-territorial powers, transfer <strong>of</strong> functions from subordinate structures to<br />
higher local government bodies, voluntary associations between municipalities<br />
and special districts. The more far-reaching options include the consolidation <strong>of</strong><br />
areas, the separation <strong>of</strong> previously joint structures, the metropolitan federalist<br />
structures, as well as the uni-city models.<br />
4.1 Moderate approaches to establishing metropolitan governments<br />
Metropolitan governance may arise through annexation. In this arrangement, a<br />
city brings within its jurisdiction others falling within a metropolitan area. <strong>No</strong><br />
major changes in organisation are brought about, and this option is likely to face<br />
less political resistance. In <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, the combination <strong>of</strong> urban and rural<br />
areas has been proposed. The second arrangement is the extension <strong>of</strong> extraterritorial<br />
powers to a new area. The powers referred to may include service<br />
delivery powers and regulations. Typical services for this type <strong>of</strong> arrangements<br />
are water provision, city dumps et cetera, where these would be efficient. While<br />
the extension <strong>of</strong> service provision may not necessarily raise political problems,<br />
the extension <strong>of</strong> regulations may be controversial. The third option may be the<br />
transfer <strong>of</strong> functions from a subordinate to a high structure. Functions likely to<br />
be taken away from the former may include property assessments. In the White<br />
Paper on local government, the powers <strong>of</strong> substructures have been withdrawn<br />
32
in the areas <strong>of</strong> rating, approval <strong>of</strong> budgets and the raising <strong>of</strong> loans. The kind <strong>of</strong><br />
move may in certain instances trigger political opposition. Another possible<br />
arrangement may be voluntary associations. This should encourage cooperation<br />
on area-wide issues. Representatives from member municipalities may<br />
collaborate to facilitate communication and research. While these arrangements<br />
may be useful, they are unlikely to address the gross inequities that are<br />
visible in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. It is unlikely that individual municipalities would voluntarily<br />
bind themselves to areas not falling within their jurisdictions. Another<br />
option may be the creation <strong>of</strong> special districts. These are independent, autonomous<br />
units <strong>of</strong> government with own taxing and borrowing powers. Special<br />
districts are likely to be involved in revenue producing activities, such as toll<br />
roads and bridges, tunnels and public transport. In this context, special district<br />
arrangements are able to take advantage <strong>of</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> scale as they can<br />
design their own boundaries. Special districts are not very likely to experience<br />
political resistance, as they tend not to be political entities. The major shortcoming<br />
<strong>of</strong> these arrangements, as hinted in the Asian experience, is that they<br />
look at service provision from a narrow perspective. A service may be rendered<br />
efficiently when looked at on its own, but not so when the overall priorities <strong>of</strong> the<br />
area in question are taken into consideration (Goodall 1968). The need for<br />
complementarity and synergy in the way services are rendered becomes critical.<br />
It seems quite unlikely that the options spelt out above will be appropriate on<br />
their own. These arrangements are unlikely to have the required capacity to<br />
face hard decisions such as land-use planning and redistribution. The voluntary<br />
arrangement, in particular, is likely to concentrate on issues around which<br />
conflict is not likely to surface. Annexation, unaccompanied by a proper system<br />
<strong>of</strong> intergovernmental transfers from the provincial and national governments,<br />
may simply render a system <strong>of</strong> local government unworkable. The systematic<br />
collection <strong>of</strong> socioeconomic information about an area, in order to determine<br />
needs, should form the basis <strong>of</strong> these transfers.<br />
4.2 Far-reaching approaches to establishing metropolitan types <strong>of</strong><br />
local government<br />
The far-reaching changes seem to be more applicable in the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n<br />
context. The first <strong>of</strong> these may be the bringing together <strong>of</strong> similar local government<br />
structures, into one big metropolitan structure. This may be considered<br />
an option for this particular area. Where this is likely to result in the rationalisation<br />
<strong>of</strong> the elected <strong>of</strong>ficials and/or appointed ones, resistance may be ex-<br />
33
perienced to this form <strong>of</strong> establishment. In areas <strong>of</strong> conflict and duplication<br />
between functions performed by the metropolitan council and the substructure,<br />
a possible option may be the consolidation <strong>of</strong> the two structures into one<br />
metropolitan council. There may be fears <strong>of</strong> loss <strong>of</strong> autonomy in this arrangement<br />
on the part <strong>of</strong> a substructure that had been independent. When a metropolitan<br />
substructure has attained a state <strong>of</strong> self-sufficiency, its separation<br />
from the metropolitan councils may be an appropriate option. The potential<br />
danger with this type <strong>of</strong> arrangement is that it may set a precedent for similar<br />
organisations to secede, which may not always be in the broader, metro-wide<br />
interest. The other option is what may be referred to as the metropolitan-federalist<br />
option. In this arrangement, the Metropolitan Council takes responsibility<br />
for general functions, such as the provision <strong>of</strong> bulk infrastructure, while the<br />
substructures are responsible for very localised functions. The workability <strong>of</strong><br />
this arrangement depends on the powers <strong>of</strong> the said types <strong>of</strong> local government.<br />
When the Metropolitan Councils do not have sufficient powers, their equalisation<br />
efforts may be undermined by lower-level structures. In particular, when the<br />
lower-level structures have the powers to collect rateable property tax, they<br />
may be reluctant to use the tax in other areas.<br />
An option that seems to be gaining increasing favour in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, is what is<br />
referred to as the uni-city, or mega-city option. Under this arrangement, all<br />
powers are vested in the Metropolitan Council, and it is their discretion to decide<br />
which functions may be devolved. The White Paper on Local Government has<br />
in fact even excluded certain powers from those that may be devolved. The<br />
powers that may not be devolved include the approval <strong>of</strong> budgets and the<br />
determination <strong>of</strong> property ratings. The uni-city model seems able to achieve<br />
some level <strong>of</strong> redistribution (Wooldridge 1998:21). It has to be borne in mind on<br />
the other hand that local government cannot be left with the sole redistributive<br />
function. National and provincial governments need to design a proper system<br />
<strong>of</strong> intergovernmental fiscal transfers, as local authorities cannot address all<br />
poverty problems in urban areas. The major shortcoming <strong>of</strong> the uni-city model<br />
may be its tendency to become distant from the electorate. For that reason, the<br />
establishment <strong>of</strong> lower-level structures for the mobilisation <strong>of</strong> grassroots views<br />
remains a necessity. Hopefully this will be realised through the establishment <strong>of</strong><br />
Ward Councils and substructures, as spelt out both in the White Paper and<br />
related legislation. These structures have limited powers, but may also expect<br />
to have certain powers devolved to them.<br />
Whether these arrangements will work remains an issue that needs to be<br />
34
closely monitored. However, it would appear from the Asian experience that for<br />
metropolitan government to be effective, it would need to fulfil certain minimum<br />
requirements ± a subject forming the core <strong>of</strong> the following section.<br />
5 REQUIREMENTS FOR A WORKABLE SYSTEM OF<br />
METROPOLITAN GOVERNMENT<br />
The minimum requirements for a workable system <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government,<br />
as evidenced from Asia, are: the need to integrate functions, the filling <strong>of</strong> gaps<br />
from other institutions, the reflection <strong>of</strong> tasks in the management structure, the<br />
concentration on capital facilities development as the major function, cooperation<br />
and networks with member local authorities, and local level support.<br />
The design <strong>of</strong> metropolitan management organisations should concentrate on<br />
the overall decisions on metropolitan management plans and policies. In particular,<br />
metropolitan government has to develop core expertise in choosing<br />
programmes and projects to be implemented, in allocating the requisite executive<br />
roles, and in appropriate budgeting <strong>of</strong> financial resources. The strength<br />
<strong>of</strong> a metropolitan organisation lies in its ability to take a metro-wide view <strong>of</strong> the<br />
area, to identify external opportunities and threats to its survival, as well as<br />
internal strengths and weaknesses, and to formulate clear objectives that would<br />
contextualise programmes and projects to be pursued, with clear priorities. This<br />
can for instance be done through integrated development plans.<br />
The functions <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government should not be guided by what it can<br />
do, but what others cannot do. It always needs to be borne in mind that the<br />
metropolitan option has a bias in favour <strong>of</strong> efficiency in the allocation <strong>of</strong> resources.<br />
It is not the ideal form <strong>of</strong> democratic government. Therefore, in order to<br />
function effectively, the metropolitan government needs to support the efforts <strong>of</strong><br />
other organisations that are appropriate for playing a democratic role. It is no<br />
use overloading metropolitan governments with functions other structures can<br />
perform effectively. In a situation <strong>of</strong> multiple actors, the role <strong>of</strong> metropolitan<br />
government becomes that <strong>of</strong> coordination and integration, in order to avoid both<br />
inefficiency likely to result from ill-sequenced urban development, and duplication<br />
in urban service delivery.<br />
The tasks <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government need to be reflected in the organisational<br />
structure. In certain instances, the traditional bureaucratic structure <strong>of</strong> government<br />
may not be appropriate for the proper functioning <strong>of</strong> metropolitan<br />
government. Given the integrated nature <strong>of</strong> the functions <strong>of</strong> metropolitan gov-<br />
35
ernment, the departmental approach to structuring work organisation may not<br />
be very effective. For instance, in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, one still finds many instances<br />
where infrastructure projects are driven by Engineering Departments, without<br />
cross-fertilisation with other work groups, despite the fact that infrastructural<br />
programmes have wider social, institutional, financial and environmental dimensions.<br />
There is a constant need to reflect this integrated nature in the<br />
design <strong>of</strong> work teams.<br />
In surveys conducted in Asian cities, it has become obvious that capital budgeting<br />
should be a principal function <strong>of</strong> metropolitan governments (Sivaramakrishnan<br />
& Green 1986). In a <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n survey <strong>of</strong> local government<br />
budgets for the 1996/7 financial year, it was found that capital investments<br />
constitute a significant proportion <strong>of</strong> metropolitan budgets, as table 1 shows<br />
(see Sutcliffe 1998:11).<br />
Table 1 Provincial budgets and capital expenditure (in 000's): 1996/97<br />
Province Budget Capital<br />
KWAZULU-NATAL<br />
Provincial 1 5<strong>30</strong> 797 (11%)<br />
Durban 5 282 353 1 102 616 (21%)<br />
GAUTENG<br />
Provincial 11 982 019 (8,4%)<br />
Metropolitan/urban 17 532 693 3 277 340 (19%)<br />
WESTERN CAPE<br />
Provincial 8 882 160 (25%)<br />
Cape Metro 7 458 665 2 039 324 (27%)<br />
Adapted from Further Research into metropolitan government systems (Sutcliffe 1998).<br />
Networking and cooperation amongst affected institutions is also crucial for a<br />
system <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government to work properly. Metropolitan government<br />
relies on its substructures to gauge community views and to collect information<br />
about areas. Unless the cooperation <strong>of</strong> these structures is sought, the overall<br />
36
functioning <strong>of</strong> the system may be compromised. Moreover, cooperation beyond<br />
the public sector, that is, with relevant parts <strong>of</strong> the private sector and civil<br />
society, is <strong>of</strong> the utmost importance if a metropolitan structure is to succeed.<br />
This is a particularly useful stimulus for local economic development initiatives<br />
and the cultivation <strong>of</strong> a democratic culture at the local level. Especially in <strong>South</strong><br />
<strong>Africa</strong>, metropolitan governments get a major portion <strong>of</strong> their finances from<br />
taxes from businesses in the area, making the goodwill <strong>of</strong> the latter quite critical<br />
to a sustained system <strong>of</strong> service delivery. Civil society organisations also provide<br />
metropolitan government with the requisite information about local conditions.<br />
Related to the above is the constant need for metropolitan organisations<br />
to seek legitimacy from the citizens falling within it.<br />
6 CONCLUSION<br />
This paper has attempted to spell out the issues to be borne in mind in designing<br />
a system <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government. It has done so by highlighting the<br />
kinds <strong>of</strong> factors that make a metropolitan system <strong>of</strong> government necessary. The<br />
typical functions <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government have been outlined. It has also<br />
identified, critically, institutional options for the structuring <strong>of</strong> metropolitan government<br />
to enable it to perform the functions outlined in the preceding section.<br />
Finally, it has tried to describe minimum requirements for a workable system <strong>of</strong><br />
metropolitan government.<br />
BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />
Bennett, R L 1994. Urban, local and regional restructuring. Paper prepared for IG Regional<br />
Conference, Prague.<br />
Cameron, R G 1997. The demarcation <strong>of</strong> local government boundaries. Research prepared<br />
for the White Paper on Local Government, Department <strong>of</strong> Constitutional<br />
Development, Pretoria.<br />
Goodall, L E 1968. The American metropolis. Columbus, Ohio: Merrill.<br />
Hanson, R, Margolis, J, Levin, M R & Letwin, W 1974. Reform as reorganization.<br />
Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.<br />
Sivaramakrishnan, K C & Green, L 1986. Metropolitan management: The Asian experience.<br />
Washington, DC: World Bank.<br />
Sutcliffe, M 1998. Further research into metropolitan government systems: current<br />
realities and responses to the White Paper on Local Government, prepared for<br />
Department <strong>of</strong> Constitutional Development, Pretoria.<br />
Wooldridge, D 1997. Metropolitan government. Research prepared for the Institutional<br />
Systems Cluster in preparation <strong>of</strong> the White Paper on Local Government, Department<br />
<strong>of</strong> Constitutional Development, Pretoria.<br />
37
Indicators for indigenous financial<br />
efforts: theory, evidence and<br />
prospects 1<br />
N J Vermaak<br />
ABSTRACT<br />
This paper evaluates indigenous financial efforts (IFEs) in rural areas in<br />
terms <strong>of</strong> their contribution to rural community development. It will be argued<br />
that IFEs are <strong>of</strong>ten associated and evaluated with quantitative criteria in spite<br />
<strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>ound non-economic benefits such schemes have for community<br />
development. Evidence from success stories in the developing world and<br />
fieldwork done in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> reveal that successful IFEs are <strong>of</strong>ten determined<br />
by indicators <strong>of</strong> a qualitative nature and that the non-economic<br />
attributes <strong>of</strong> IFEs support and facilitate local development.<br />
1 INTRODUCTION<br />
Since agriculture is an important economic activity in the developing world<br />
(Todaro 1997: 295) and, in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>'s case, will be so for at least another<br />
two or three decades (Van Aardt 1997: 263), financial initiatives are much<br />
needed to accommodate the rural poor ± something which is <strong>of</strong>ten considered<br />
irreconcilable with the objectives <strong>of</strong> NGOs, such as realising pr<strong>of</strong>its in order to<br />
be successful (Schoombee 1998: 390).<br />
During the 1970s, when economic development was recognised to be the<br />
dominant paradigm, scant attention was <strong>of</strong>ten paid to non-economic benefits <strong>of</strong><br />
financial incentives in rural areas. In this report it will be argued that indigenous<br />
rural financial efforts (IFEs) are in many instances mainly evaluated with<br />
quantitative criteria, in spite <strong>of</strong> the existence <strong>of</strong> non-economic benefits that are<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>nus <strong>30</strong>(2)2000 38
not only a central success determinant for IFEs, but also support local community<br />
development.<br />
Evidence will be presented from successful cases <strong>of</strong> IFEs in the developing<br />
world and fieldwork done in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. The first case is that <strong>of</strong> Ghana, where<br />
the Susu collectors are used to mobilise savings in rural areas. Secondly, the<br />
Grameen Bank in Bangladesh illustrates that the loyalty and dedication <strong>of</strong> the<br />
Bangladeshi women contribute to the success <strong>of</strong> the financial scheme. The third<br />
case is the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n one, where stokvels, rotating savings clubs and village<br />
banks contribute to community development in a number <strong>of</strong> ways, such as<br />
employment creation, support for microentrepreneurs, enhancing group autonomy<br />
and improving the status <strong>of</strong> women. The results <strong>of</strong> fieldwork done in<br />
Levhuvhu in the <strong>No</strong>rthern Province <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> will also be discussed.<br />
After the indicators for successful IFEs have been identified both theoretically<br />
and by means <strong>of</strong> case studies, I will suggest a grouping <strong>of</strong> the indicators, firstly<br />
to ``create order'' and secondly, hopefully to be <strong>of</strong> help when the success <strong>of</strong><br />
IFEs is assessed in terms <strong>of</strong> rural community development. The indicators will<br />
be grouped into quantitative, qualitative and partly quantitative categories. I will<br />
also argue that the prospects <strong>of</strong> sustaining successful IFEs depend on the<br />
interrelatedness <strong>of</strong> quantifiable, partly quantifiable and qualitative success attributes.<br />
In the next section attention will be given to some viewpoints <strong>of</strong> what successful<br />
IFEs should entail.<br />
2 IDENTIFYING APPROPRIATE INDICATORS<br />
Biased viewpoints regarding the failure or success <strong>of</strong> a financial effort and/or<br />
irrelevant indicators may be problematic for evaluators, particularly when one<br />
considers that what matters is not only how financial schemes are evaluated,<br />
but also who sets the evaluation criteria. One <strong>of</strong> the main dangers, as noted by<br />
Wetmore and Theron (1998: <strong>30</strong>) and Conyers and Kaul (1990: 129), is that the<br />
views <strong>of</strong> ``outsiders'' (such as donors and national governments) will prevail<br />
over those <strong>of</strong> the intended community members. The researcher's own position<br />
(eg the type <strong>of</strong> institution represented) becomes questionable and, according to<br />
Oosthuizen and Van der Worm (1991: 14), may facilitate or complicate the<br />
researcher's entrance into the setting.<br />
Since the indicators for community development vary, they may be sifted by<br />
39
dividing them into three interrelated categories, namely quantitative, partly<br />
quantifiable, and qualitative indicators. Conyers and Kaul (1990: 129) point out<br />
that quantifiable indicators reflect an important element <strong>of</strong> development, ie a<br />
community's wellbeing. Key features <strong>of</strong> this category <strong>of</strong> indicators are that they<br />
are concrete, visible and can be measured. Indicators such as health, clothes,<br />
water supply, education, employment, household incomes and demography are<br />
examples <strong>of</strong> quantifiable community indicators. Partly quantifiable indicators<br />
are indicators that contain both quantifiable and qualitative attributes. This<br />
group <strong>of</strong> indicators, which may also be labelled intermediate or ``grey area''<br />
indicators, can only be quantified to a limited extent and changes may only be<br />
partly visible. Unlike the quantifiable and partly quantifiable indicators, qualitative<br />
indicators are highly abstract and include indicators such as aspirations,<br />
perceptions and attitudes. Swanepoel (1997: 67) notes that the psychological<br />
environments <strong>of</strong> communities may be different and, because <strong>of</strong> their abstract<br />
nature, are <strong>of</strong>ten ignored. Personal contact between interviewer(s) and respondent(s)<br />
is essential to obtain qualitative information which cannot ordinarily<br />
be obtained by means <strong>of</strong> formal questionnaires (Cobett 1987: 333).<br />
In view <strong>of</strong> this wide spectrum <strong>of</strong> indicators, it is ironic that successful IFEs are in<br />
practice predominantly rated in terms <strong>of</strong> quantitative economic criteria. Adams<br />
(1992: 6±7) points out that two schools <strong>of</strong> thought exist on how success should<br />
be measured in rural financial activities: the credit-project view and the marketperformance<br />
view. Designers and evaluators <strong>of</strong> rural credit projects, who belong<br />
to the first school, view loans in terms <strong>of</strong> productive inputs such as loans<br />
made to target group members, the inputs purchased with loans, an increased<br />
output through borrowing, and changes in income or employment levels among<br />
borrowers. Supporters <strong>of</strong> the market-performance view contend that attention<br />
should rather be paid to deposit mobilisation, intermediary behaviour, lowering<br />
transaction cost, effective financial innovations, building sustainable financial<br />
services and the extent to which policies affect the performance <strong>of</strong> rural financial<br />
markets.<br />
Writers also report a substantial number <strong>of</strong> quantitative criteria: Kraft<br />
(1996: 215±216) lists a number <strong>of</strong> features which are shared by successful rural<br />
financial schemes, for example conductive macroeconomic, agricultural and<br />
rural policies, and a relatively stable political environment; investment in rural<br />
infrastructure; innovative and flexible (market-oriented) lending rates; strong<br />
controls to limit expenditures and administrative costs; and close monitoring <strong>of</strong><br />
loan performance with high collection rates and low arrears. Coetzee and Vink<br />
40
(1996: 257) also use a quantitative categorisation <strong>of</strong> success indicators, containing<br />
popular economic parameters: outreach indicators (such as the number<br />
<strong>of</strong> branches and deposit accounts, outstanding loans and loan size), productivity<br />
indicators (such as loans and volume lent to staff and <strong>of</strong>ficers and the<br />
percentage <strong>of</strong> loans in arrears) and pr<strong>of</strong>itability indicators (such as the percentage<br />
return on capital, loan and deposit rate and the gross financial margin).<br />
These views suggest that, in measuring the success <strong>of</strong> rural financial activities,<br />
quantifiable indicators are heavily emphasised. Little or no attention is frequently<br />
given to indicators <strong>of</strong> a qualitative nature, which, hypothetically<br />
speaking, appear to be equally essential not only for financial sustainability, but<br />
also for the development <strong>of</strong> the broader rural community. In the next section<br />
``success stories'' from the Developing World are <strong>of</strong>fered.<br />
3 FINANCIAL SCHEMES IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD<br />
According to Todaro (1997: <strong>30</strong>±31) the Developing Nations <strong>of</strong> the world are<br />
located in Asia, Latin America and <strong>Africa</strong>. The following cases, selected from<br />
West <strong>Africa</strong>, Asia and <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, serve as only a few instances <strong>of</strong> the success<br />
IFEs enjoyed in facilitating community development.<br />
Ghana's rural areas are typical <strong>of</strong> many other areas in the Developing World<br />
where banks are ill equipped or nonexistent and rural communities' access to<br />
formal financial services is severely hampered by infrastructural problems. In<br />
Ghana's rural areas individual mobile bankers (known as Susu collectors) fulfil<br />
a particular useful function (Spio, Groenewald & Coetzee 1995: 257). Susu<br />
collectors collect money from their clients every day. At the end <strong>of</strong> a preset<br />
period, savings are returned to the depositors, less the commission cost <strong>of</strong> the<br />
Susu intermediate. This IFE empowers Ghana's rural communities in many<br />
ways, for instance, it helps households to anticipate dry seasons, which, in turn,<br />
provides a form <strong>of</strong> security and control over the communities' circumstances. In<br />
southern Ghana, for example, incomes are becoming generally less seasonal<br />
and cyclical, although large portions <strong>of</strong> rural savings are still held in less liquid<br />
forms such as building materials, partially completed construction projects and<br />
cleared land (Aryeety 1996: 129). Susu collectors are widely trusted in Ghana's<br />
rural communities and, latently, also play a role in the communication processes<br />
in their communities.<br />
Wahid (1994: 1±14) reports that the Grameen Bank (``grameen'' means rural) in<br />
Bangladesh has initiated a mechanism under which the rural poor may have<br />
41
access to credit on a group liability basis instead <strong>of</strong> any collateral. Initial loans<br />
are granted to small groups <strong>of</strong> people. Before loans are allocated, these groups<br />
must first demonstrate a weekly pattern <strong>of</strong> saving. Since the Grameen Bank<br />
started in 1976, it has expanded to more than <strong>30</strong>0 branches in over 5 400<br />
villages, catering for 250 000 people in Bangladesh, mostly women. Available<br />
evidence suggests that the repayment rate is much better than in the Bangladeshi<br />
commercial banking system: 97 percent <strong>of</strong> all Grameen loans are repaid<br />
within one year and 99 percent within two years (Todaro 1997: 616). Indicators<br />
such as an unprecedented loan recovery rate, an increase in the Grameen<br />
Bank members' agricultural productivity and their per capita income, and an<br />
improvement in their nutrition, housing and general living conditions, signal that<br />
the Grameen Bank is successful (see Kraft 1996: 215±216). Wahid (1994: 12)<br />
notes that some qualitative indicators such as the loyalty and dedication <strong>of</strong> the<br />
field workers in particular contribute to the sustainability <strong>of</strong> the Grameen Bank.<br />
In <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> different types <strong>of</strong> savings schemes are commonly used among<br />
rural people. Spio et al (1995: 256) identify the following: savings in the form <strong>of</strong><br />
food, cattle and other livestock (see Aryeety 1996: 128), stokvels representing<br />
a type <strong>of</strong> rotating savings and credit associations (ROSCAs), unorthodox savings<br />
which include the hoarding <strong>of</strong> money in small boxes in the house, under<br />
pillows, buried money or money given to another institution for safekeeping.<br />
People may also trust each other with their savings. Pensioners in particular are<br />
<strong>of</strong>ten trusted with loans.<br />
There are three particular examples in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> <strong>of</strong> successful IFEs supporting<br />
and sustaining development on the local level. Firstly, in the Eastern<br />
Cape (the southern part <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>) Buijs (1998: 55, 63±64) conducted an<br />
investigation among men and women ± all members <strong>of</strong> ROSCAs ± and found<br />
that participation in ROSCAs act as a support mechanism for poor women's<br />
search for income-earning activities and as a means <strong>of</strong> maximising their resources.<br />
Buijs (1998: 63) also found that the notion <strong>of</strong> risk featured as an<br />
essential personal ingredient amongst poor women belonging to ROSCAs.<br />
Secondly, stokvels, which are well known to local rural people, comprising<br />
(similar to ROSCAs) saving and credit schemes and also a form <strong>of</strong> insurance.<br />
Similar associations may be found in Mexico, Bolivia, Egypt, Nigeria, the Philippines,<br />
Sri Lanka, China and <strong>South</strong> Korea (Todaro 1997: 616). Thirdly, village<br />
banks implemented during <strong>No</strong>vember 1994 in villages in the <strong>No</strong>rthwest Province,<br />
serve as an example <strong>of</strong> ample community participation and community<br />
support contributing to the success <strong>of</strong> the scheme. Village banks are commu-<br />
42
nity-managed savings and credit institutions (Schoombee 1998: 391) and have<br />
already been successfully implemented in several rural villages like Kraaipan,<br />
Modimola, Madikwe and Motsedi. Unlike ROSCAs and stokvels, village banks<br />
<strong>of</strong>fer products such as shares, accounts, fixed deposits, transmissions,<br />
vouchers, loans and insurance to its members (Schoeman 1996: 8±9).<br />
Some other examples frequently cited as successful rural financial institutions<br />
are: the Badan Kredit Kecamatan (BKK) programme <strong>of</strong> a provincial development<br />
bank in Central Java (Schoombee 1998: 391), the Bank for Agriculture<br />
and Agricultural Cooperatives in Thailand and the village banks (``Unit Desas'')<br />
<strong>of</strong> Bank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI) (Kraft 1996: 215). Despite the significant differences<br />
among rural financial schemes (such as size, benefits and operation<br />
mode) trust, participation and internal support are also prominent success indicators<br />
in most instances.<br />
The following case study endeavoured to seek additional practical indicators <strong>of</strong><br />
community facilitation through successful IFEs.<br />
4 CASE STUDY: THE STOKVEL SCHEMES IN LEVHUVHU<br />
Levhuvhu is situated in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>'s <strong>No</strong>rthern Province. In 1995 the Development<br />
Bank <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong>ern <strong>Africa</strong> (DBSA 1995: 15) reported that the <strong>No</strong>rthern<br />
Province remained the poorest <strong>of</strong> the nine provinces in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Its<br />
economy also had the lowest labour absorption capacity, resulting in the<br />
highest unemployment rate in the country. IFEs can however be found in the<br />
local rural communities as the case <strong>of</strong> Levhuvhu clearly shows.<br />
Levhuvhu is situated in the Louis Trichardt municipal area, near Venda, one <strong>of</strong><br />
the former ``homelands'' <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>'s previous dispensation. Levhuvhu is<br />
characterised by two worlds: affluent white commercial farmers and a large<br />
population <strong>of</strong> black small-scale peasant farmers and workers. Seasonal fruits<br />
such as mangos, litchis, pineapples, macadamia nuts, avocados and bananas<br />
are commercially cultivated on Levhuvhu. Some workers commute from their<br />
villages, but most <strong>of</strong> them stay on the farms where they work. Low salaries<br />
(resulting from the oversupply <strong>of</strong> labour), poor drinking, cooking and washing<br />
facilities and generally low standards <strong>of</strong> living prevail in most <strong>of</strong> these peasant<br />
households ± circumstances which are worsened by rudimentary services and<br />
the recent catastrophic flooding in the region.<br />
The lack <strong>of</strong> accurate statistics is <strong>of</strong>ten a great problem in rural areas. Levhuvhu<br />
43
is no exception. Since the researcher was residing in Levhuvhu during the time<br />
<strong>of</strong> the investigation, the data could be collected systematically over an eightmonth<br />
period. Semiformal interviews were conducted during this time with 50<br />
men and women in the Levhuvhu district. These respondents were very open<br />
and willing to talk about their membership <strong>of</strong> rural financial schemes. <strong>No</strong>tes<br />
were taken during the field work and afterwards the respondents' feedback was<br />
consolidated on a summarised answer sheet.<br />
Independent moneylenders, who charge extremely high interest rates, may be<br />
found in the adjacent villages. Pensioners are paid monthly, mostly at banks in<br />
the formal sector, <strong>of</strong> which the closest are about 40 kilometres away in<br />
neighbouring towns. On pension payout days, people frequently queue halfway<br />
around the street block. IFEs in the form <strong>of</strong> informal savings and credit are very<br />
well known in Levhuvhu and, on investigation, proved to be popular activities.<br />
This is evident from the lively discussions during stokvel meetings which take<br />
place regularly, and the respondents' knowledge about the structure and<br />
functioning <strong>of</strong> savings and credit schemes. Stokvel meetings are entertaining<br />
social gatherings, where talk is not only about money, but also about personal<br />
and communal experiences. Stokvel meetings are mostly held on a monthly<br />
basis. During these meetings food and drinks are provided. The women, who<br />
clearly play a dominant role in terms <strong>of</strong> ROSCAs membership, displayed an<br />
enthusiastic and proud attitude towards their particular savings and/or credit<br />
scheme.<br />
A number <strong>of</strong> dramatic cases <strong>of</strong> financial ``rescues'' were reported by the respondents.<br />
In one instance a woman, belonging to a stokvel and selling tomatoes<br />
for a living, reported that the money she saved up during the year<br />
contributed to the sustainability <strong>of</strong> her small business during the post Christmas/<br />
New Year period. Her place on the pavement could stay occupied and therefore<br />
she did not risk losing her trading space. Members <strong>of</strong> a stokvel are required to<br />
specify their household members, since the stokvel, like many other ROSCAs,<br />
assist their members in times <strong>of</strong> financial need such as weddings and funerals.<br />
This is covered by a monthly premium <strong>of</strong> 20 to 50 rand. Savings and credit<br />
stokvels mostly pay individual members on a rotating basis. A number <strong>of</strong> relatively<br />
small stokvels exist in Levhuvhu: some <strong>of</strong> them have only 3±8 members.<br />
Since we started the fieldwork, it became clear that becoming a stokvel member<br />
depended purely on the personal characteristics <strong>of</strong> the potential members, such<br />
as their creditworthiness and their relationship to an existing group member.<br />
44
Stokvels and ROSCAs are similar IFEs in the sense that members agree to<br />
contribute money regularly to a common pool. Buijs (1998: 62) mentions that<br />
the risk <strong>of</strong> loan repayment default is lessened in small towns and that defaulters<br />
are unlikely to be accepted as members <strong>of</strong> other associations. Members are<br />
keen to keep their status as stokvel members and are likely to conform to the<br />
underlying norms and requirements <strong>of</strong> the group like honesty, reliability and<br />
discipline.<br />
One also becomes aware <strong>of</strong> the symbolism and ``invisible'' processes which<br />
appear to be part <strong>of</strong> the everyday lives <strong>of</strong> the people in Levhuvhu. Throughout<br />
the fieldwork one word emerged: ubuntu. The term is different in every <strong>Africa</strong>n<br />
dialect, but the meaning is always roughly the same: a complex, yet highly<br />
nuanced precept governing the way individuals relate to the community. Ubuntu<br />
is a regulatory norm which places the interest <strong>of</strong> the community above the<br />
individual (McGeary & Michaels 1998: 48). Vhuthu is the TshiVenda equivalent.<br />
Working together helps to foster a climate <strong>of</strong> consensus, functional conflict and<br />
the achievement <strong>of</strong> goals. Although there are few if any written instructions<br />
about the stokvel members' use <strong>of</strong> their money, informal forces such as codes<br />
and taboos require the money to be used in an ``appropriate'' manner, presumably<br />
as a countermeasure against bad individual decision making. Stokvel<br />
members mostly spend their money on clothes, food, school books and<br />
household utensils. During stokvel meetings the somewhat conventional, but<br />
highly effective ``bush telegraph'' distributes information quickly amongst the<br />
participants. Information is also shared with other members in the broader<br />
Levhuvhu community. The manner in which economic transactions are carried<br />
out is also <strong>of</strong>ten symbolic. Watson (1989: 22±24) notes that economic exchanges<br />
such as land, tobacco, cannabis, gold and roosters may occur in rural<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>n societies. In Levhuvhu, roosters and cows can be identified as having<br />
particular symbolic associations.<br />
From the interviews conducted with the respondents, it seems that the membership<br />
<strong>of</strong> a stokvel association contributes to community development in<br />
various ways. For example, in Levhuvhu access to informal credit has contributed<br />
to the support <strong>of</strong> microentrepreneurs who, in turn, are part <strong>of</strong> day-to-day<br />
rural community life. Financial incentives such as the Grameen Bank, ROSCAs<br />
and even stokvels may provide a viable platform from which managerial capabilities<br />
(such as financial control and innovation) could be supported. Women<br />
are empowered, which may lead to an improvement <strong>of</strong> their political, social,<br />
economic and health status. This is essential for the achievement <strong>of</strong> sustainable<br />
45
development and the implementation <strong>of</strong> population development programmes<br />
(Todaro 1997: 225).<br />
All the cases discussed above suggest that IFEs will succeed in instances<br />
where members share in the benefits <strong>of</strong>fered by such an effort ± direct or<br />
indirect, concrete or abstract. Various rural communities may have different<br />
reasons for participating and different ways <strong>of</strong> doing so; and the reasons for<br />
failures are not always clear to Western thinkers. The advantages to participants<br />
<strong>of</strong> IFEs are not only quantitative (like money and houses), but also partly<br />
quantifiable (such as community control, autonomy and participation) and<br />
qualitative ( such as the enhancement <strong>of</strong> social standing, obtaining responsibility,<br />
and the building or expansion <strong>of</strong> social networks). Women are particularly<br />
empowered. From Levhuvhu's case it can be concluded that, despite the incidence<br />
<strong>of</strong> poverty, membership <strong>of</strong> a stokvel financial scheme fulfils a stabilising,<br />
harmonising and supportive function in the Levhuvhu communities'<br />
development discourse. The success indicators, implied collectively by the<br />
successful cases <strong>of</strong> IFEs discussed above, include: the empowerment <strong>of</strong> women,<br />
the sense <strong>of</strong> belonging to a community (with the accompanying benefits<br />
such as identity and security), mutual trustworthiness, competition, leadership,<br />
adaptation to local circumstances, capability, risk, morality, social standing and<br />
status, solidarity, reputation, loyalty, honesty, discipline, dedication, community<br />
control and hope.<br />
5 PROSPECTS FOR IFEs IN RURAL COMMUNITIES<br />
For IFEs to succeed, and for communities to obtain support from IFEs on a<br />
sustainable basis, the following has to be considered:<br />
With regard to quantitative, partly quantitative and qualitative indicators it is<br />
especially the latter two categories <strong>of</strong> indicators which feature as key determinants<br />
<strong>of</strong> successful IFEs and, hence, support development in local rural<br />
communities. In all the cases mentioned above, quantitative indicators <strong>of</strong> successful<br />
IFE schemes do have a significant role to play in terms <strong>of</strong> community<br />
socioeconomic prosperity. An increase in household incomes is necessary to<br />
satisfy people's basic needs. However, in Levhuvhu's case, the invisible qualitative<br />
dimension appears to overshadow materialistic gains. Keeping in mind<br />
that most stokvel members do not receive favourable ratings by formal institutions,<br />
the qualitative benefits experienced by these ``uncreditworthy'' par-<br />
46
ticipants and the way in which rural communities in the developing world adapt<br />
to their circumstances are indeed remarkable.<br />
Furthermore, structural changes in the global economy appear to influence the<br />
prospects for successful rural financing in at least three ways. Firstly, rapid<br />
progress in information technology has opened new possibilities for (and<br />
threats to) rural communities. From advances in telecommunication and information<br />
technology it is clear that formal financial services will soon be<br />
available in remote rural areas not previously considered for this purpose. The<br />
rapid pace <strong>of</strong> global structural development could have severe implications for<br />
the sustainability <strong>of</strong> IFEs and may increase the marginalisation <strong>of</strong> rural communities<br />
(Van Aardt 1997: 256±257). Secondly, the formal and informal sectors<br />
may be integrated; both Schoombee (1998: 391) and Germidis (1990: 18±21)<br />
advocate this possibility. This integration may be achieved by improving the<br />
formal financial sector, developing the social insurance sector and ``organising''<br />
the informal sector. This may also be done by assisting rural communities with<br />
the establishment <strong>of</strong> supportive policies, by encouraging appropriate technologies<br />
and indigenous knowledge, and by providing managerial training to participants<br />
in rural financial schemes. The Strauss Commission (Strauss 1996: 6,<br />
14±15) recommends using the Post Office 2 to satisfy the basic financial service<br />
needs <strong>of</strong> the poorest segment <strong>of</strong> the rural population. Finally, and most importantly,<br />
political interference and state regulation will support financial service<br />
provision in local economies. With the presence <strong>of</strong> political will, both multidisciplinary<br />
research and human-centred development can be brought to the<br />
poor in rural communities.<br />
6 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION<br />
This article presented theoretical and practical perspectives from which may be<br />
concluded that economic indicators still are the dominant paradigm, in spite <strong>of</strong> a<br />
reported shift to a human-centred approach in development in the last two<br />
decades. From the case studies in the developing world in which a number <strong>of</strong><br />
successful IFEs were introduced, it is clear that indicators <strong>of</strong> a quantifiable,<br />
partly quantifiable and ± in many instances ± <strong>of</strong> a purely qualitative nature,<br />
indeed prevail and serve as resources for rural communities in both economic<br />
and social terms. In the cases <strong>of</strong> ROSCAs and stokvels it is clear that women<br />
are particularly empowered, not only by the increase in their income, but also by<br />
the satisfaction <strong>of</strong> their abstract psychological needs such as security and<br />
status. In most instances IFEs will therefore require multidisciplinary research.<br />
47
Prospects for the sustainability <strong>of</strong> IFEs will depend on many factors, <strong>of</strong> which<br />
internal and external support are the most essential. I conclude by suggesting<br />
that if an IFE is to be ``measured'' against the benefits to the broader community,<br />
partly quantifiable and qualitative measures should in all instances (and<br />
in particular) be considered by all evaluators involved.<br />
ENDNOTES<br />
1 An earlier version <strong>of</strong> this paper was presented as a discussion paper during a<br />
workshop at a conference in Edinburgh, Scotland.<br />
2 Account payments, credit functions and savings mobilisation.<br />
BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />
Adams, D W 1992. Building durable financial markets in <strong>Africa</strong>. <strong>Africa</strong>n Review <strong>of</strong><br />
Money, Finance and Banking (1):5±14.<br />
Aryeetey, E 1996. Formal and informal economic activities, in <strong>Africa</strong> now: people, policies<br />
and institutions, edited by S Ellis. Portsmouth: NH: Heinemann:119±135.<br />
Buijs, G 1998. Savings and loan clubs: risky ventures or good business practice? A study<br />
<strong>of</strong> the importance <strong>of</strong> rotating savings and credit associations for poor women.<br />
Development <strong>South</strong>ern <strong>Africa</strong> 15(1):55±65.<br />
Cobett, M 1987. Community projects: the possibilities in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Development<br />
<strong>South</strong>ern <strong>Africa</strong> 4(2):324±340.<br />
Coetzee, G & Vink, N 1996. The efficiency and outreach <strong>of</strong> rural financial institutions in<br />
<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Agrecon 35(4):256±260.<br />
Conyers, D & Kaul, M 1990. Strategic issues in development management: learning from<br />
successful experience, part 1. Development Management 10:127±141.<br />
Development Bank <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong>ern <strong>Africa</strong> (DBSA) 1995. <strong>No</strong>rthern Province: statistical review,<br />
compiled by C J Meintjies, B G Rousseau & D J Viljoen. Midrand. (Development<br />
Information Paper 103.)<br />
Germidis, D 1990. Interlinking the formal and informal financial sectors in developing<br />
countries. Savings and Development 1(15):5±21.<br />
Kraft, N J 1996. Agricultural and rural finance: some thoughts on the road ahead.<br />
Agrekon 35(4):211±217.<br />
McGeary, J & Michaels, M 1998. <strong>Africa</strong> rising. Time 151(13):38±48.<br />
Oosthuizen, C J & Van der Worm, Y 1991. Ecosystemic epistemology in community<br />
intervention in <strong>Africa</strong>: a case report. Paper presented at the Third World Family<br />
Therapy Congress, Jyvaskyla, Finland.<br />
Schoeman, J H 1996. Village bank: project description. Financial Service Association<br />
(FSA), Eldoraigne.<br />
Schoombee, A 1998. The financial systems approach to development finance: origin,<br />
evolution and prospects. Development <strong>South</strong>ern <strong>Africa</strong> 15(3):379±398.<br />
48
Spio, K, Groenewald, J A & Coetzee, G K 1995. Savings mobilization in rural areas:<br />
lessons from experience. Agrekon 34(4):254±259.<br />
Strauss, C B (Chairman) 1996. Final Report <strong>of</strong> the Commission <strong>of</strong> Inquiry into the<br />
Provision <strong>of</strong> Rural Financial Services.<br />
Swanepoel, H 1997. Community development: putting plans into action. Kenwyn: Juta.<br />
Todaro, M P 1997. Economic development in the Third World. 6th edition. New York:<br />
Longman.<br />
Van Aardt, M 1997. Factors influencing development prospects for <strong>South</strong>ern <strong>Africa</strong>, in<br />
Change and <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n external relations, edited by W Carlsnaes & M Muller.<br />
Halfway House: International Thomson:252±265.<br />
Wahid, A N M 1994. The Grameen Bank and poverty alleviation in Bangladesh: theory,<br />
evidence and limitations. The American Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics and Sociology<br />
53(1):1±15.<br />
Watson, J L (ed) 1989. Bitter money: cultural economy and some <strong>Africa</strong>n meanings <strong>of</strong><br />
forbidden commodities. Washington, DC: Parker Shipton.<br />
Wetmore, S B & Theron, F 1998. Community development and research: participatory<br />
leaming and action ± a development strategy in itself. Development <strong>South</strong>ern<br />
<strong>Africa</strong> 15(1):29±54.<br />
49
Gender relations: a missing link in<br />
Third World development planning<br />
Tsepiso Mohapi<br />
ABSTRACT<br />
In the first decades after the Second World War, the pursuit <strong>of</strong> economic<br />
development was reflected in the almost universal acceptance <strong>of</strong> development<br />
planning as the surest and most direct route to economic progress by<br />
most, if not all, Third World countries. As indicated by UNESCO (1986), from<br />
the 1950s development planning has been oriented towards achieving<br />
economic growth above all, for it was assumed that the benefits <strong>of</strong> economic<br />
growth had an automatic tendency to trickle down to the poorer sections <strong>of</strong><br />
society. Development plans were assumed to benefit all people and affect<br />
them in the same way. Planners have always thought that if men as assumed<br />
heads <strong>of</strong> households benefit from development efforts, so will their<br />
families. Little consideration has been given to the multiple roles <strong>of</strong> women in<br />
society. Because women's active participation in development activities is<br />
frequently unremunerated, it is <strong>of</strong>ten unaccounted for in national statistics.<br />
The underlying reason is that women's activities are home based and related<br />
to taking care <strong>of</strong> the household, while men are engaged in income-generating<br />
activities for their families. The aim <strong>of</strong> this article is therefore to<br />
highlight the implications <strong>of</strong> planned development for women since the 1950s<br />
when development planning first came into the international spotlight.<br />
INTRODUCTION<br />
According to Allan and Thomas (1992:294),<br />
gender relations are social relations referring to the way in which the social<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>nus <strong>30</strong>(2)2000 50
categories <strong>of</strong> men and women, male and female, relate over a whole range<br />
<strong>of</strong> social organisation, not just to interactions between individual men and<br />
women in the sphere <strong>of</strong> personal relationships or in terms <strong>of</strong> biological reproduction,<br />
but also in all aspects <strong>of</strong> social activity, including access to resources<br />
for production and the distribution <strong>of</strong> consumption.<br />
For the purpose <strong>of</strong> this paper, gender relations are used to refer to relations that<br />
emanate from social activities involving both men and women, and which are<br />
aimed at access to resources and their distribution.<br />
As used in this text, development planning refers to<br />
a continuous process which involves decisions, or choices, about alternative<br />
ways <strong>of</strong> using available resources, with the aim <strong>of</strong> achieving particular goals<br />
at some time in the future (Conyers & Hills 1984:3).<br />
One may add to this the major components <strong>of</strong> development planning, which<br />
include the allocation <strong>of</strong> roles and responsibilities, consultation, communication,<br />
allocating resources, locating work activities in particular places, distributing<br />
time to various activities, and monitoring and evaluating work done.<br />
Women have been excluded from these development planning activities because<br />
development planners have ignored their needs and have subjected<br />
them to conflicting demands, such as the need to earn more money and devote<br />
more time to domestic activities. Because development planning has been<br />
gender neutral since time immemorial, development efforts were thought to<br />
affect men and women in the same way before the 1970s, in spite <strong>of</strong> the fact<br />
that men and women had different perspectives and ways <strong>of</strong> working. Recently,<br />
there has been increasing awareness that as development proceeds in the<br />
Third World countries, the impact on men and women has been different.<br />
Women's participation in the overall development process has never been<br />
given full weight, because their role has not been fully understood by planners<br />
preoccupied by the need to attain improved economic development, and engaged<br />
in alleviating social, demographic and political ills at various levels <strong>of</strong> the<br />
development process. As stated by Longwe (1991), the general lack <strong>of</strong> attention<br />
to women's needs within the development process stems from lack <strong>of</strong> gender<br />
awareness amongst those who plan and implement development programmes.<br />
This therefore poses questions such as: who benefits, who loses, what trade<strong>of</strong>fs<br />
have been made, and what is the resultant balance <strong>of</strong> rights and obligations,<br />
power and privilege between men and women, and between given social<br />
51
groups? The underlying situation, as stated by Moser (1989), is that women<br />
have lost ground to men in the development process. The issue <strong>of</strong> mainstreaming<br />
gender into development planning may therefore be largely attributed<br />
to the failure <strong>of</strong> development programmes to spread their benefits equally within<br />
society. What is needed first, is a rational, systematic way <strong>of</strong> analysing the<br />
impact <strong>of</strong> development efforts on men and women, and then women have to be<br />
involved at all levels <strong>of</strong> planning. The purpose <strong>of</strong> this article is to contribute to<br />
the resolution <strong>of</strong> mainstreaming gender into development planning.<br />
20th CENTURY DEVELOPMENT PLANNING<br />
During much <strong>of</strong> the last quarter <strong>of</strong> the century, development has been viewed<br />
as the panacea for all the economic ills <strong>of</strong> less developed countries. Yet in<br />
virtually all countries and among all social classes, women have been ignored in<br />
planned development. Development that has resulted in widening gaps between<br />
incomes <strong>of</strong> men and women has not helped to improve women's lives,<br />
but rather had an adverse effect on them. Issues concerning women and their<br />
contributions in the development process have been increasingly examined<br />
over the years. However, ways <strong>of</strong> dealing with these issues have varied as the<br />
understanding <strong>of</strong> women's position in development and <strong>of</strong> gender roles has<br />
grown.<br />
The terms and evolution <strong>of</strong> debates by scholars and policy-makers on issues <strong>of</strong><br />
gender relations in development roughly emerged from the early phases <strong>of</strong><br />
development cooperation based on the economic growth and modernisation<br />
theories <strong>of</strong> the 1950s and 1960s, when development planning first came into<br />
the international spotlight. However, the role <strong>of</strong> the individual in the development<br />
process was barely addressed and even less frequently understood, as it<br />
was assumed that development efforts would benefit everybody (Charlton &<br />
Ellen 1984:1). Development was largely understood in terms <strong>of</strong> economic<br />
growth measured in GNP, instead <strong>of</strong> social wellbeing. It was assumed that<br />
economic growth brought about by modernisation would automatically improve<br />
living standards. As stated by Anand (1992:1), since the early 1950s and 1960s<br />
planned development in the <strong>No</strong>rth and <strong>South</strong> has been based on a number <strong>of</strong><br />
theories, but predominantly the ``trickle-down theory'' which assumed that as<br />
standards <strong>of</strong> living in individual countries rose, the benefits would accrue to all,<br />
including women. This belief was based on the assumption that all people are<br />
equal, in spite <strong>of</strong> the fact that history has proved otherwise and continues to do<br />
so.<br />
52
The modernisation and economic planning theories at this time focused mainly<br />
on increased productivity based on agrarian and land reforms. The green revolution<br />
<strong>of</strong> the 1960s brought about a change in agricultural production and<br />
advocated a shift from subsistence production for the domestic market to extensive<br />
production for domestic consumption as well as export, in order to<br />
generate foreign exchange much needed by the state. As indicated by Young<br />
(1992), the early 1960s saw a boom in world economy growth rates and the GIP<br />
increased by a trillion dollars as a result <strong>of</strong> the modernised agricultural strategies<br />
adopted by individual countries in the <strong>No</strong>rth and <strong>South</strong>. Although women<br />
were <strong>of</strong>ten the predominant contributors to the basic productivity in their communities,<br />
particularly in agricultural production, their economic contribution was<br />
not referred to in national statistics or development projects (Boserup 1970).<br />
The modernised projects, with innovative agricultural methods and sophisticated<br />
technologies, were negatively affecting women, displacing them from<br />
their traditional productive functions and diminishing the income status and<br />
power they had in traditional relations. Little attention was also paid to ensuring<br />
the development and integration <strong>of</strong> local and regional networks and as a result<br />
the benefits <strong>of</strong> the economic growth were not evenly distributed, with 80 percent<br />
going to the rich industrialised countries <strong>of</strong> the <strong>No</strong>rth and only 6 percent to the<br />
developing countries <strong>of</strong> the <strong>South</strong>. This enabled developed countries to move<br />
swiftly ahead (Young 1992).<br />
Although theories <strong>of</strong> modernisation and economic growth predicted that through<br />
``trickle-down effects'' all social strata would benefit from economic growth<br />
fostered by modernisation, in reality this growth was characterised by the socioeconomic<br />
marginalisation <strong>of</strong> certain sections <strong>of</strong> the population. In the late<br />
1960s, scholars who investigated quality <strong>of</strong> life found that the assumed benefits<br />
<strong>of</strong> the economic growth were in actual fact not reaching the majority <strong>of</strong> the<br />
people ± especially not the world's poorest; the majority <strong>of</strong> whom are women.<br />
Boserup (1970) thus argues that neocolonialism as much as colonialism was<br />
contributing to the declining status <strong>of</strong> women in developing countries. The resultant<br />
evidence <strong>of</strong> increasing income disparities, unemployment, rapid urbanisation<br />
and impoverishment <strong>of</strong> the minority indicated that all was not well. The<br />
``trickle-down effects'' which should have spread benefits <strong>of</strong> increasing national<br />
wealth to the mass <strong>of</strong> the population through job creation and service provision<br />
never materialised. As a result, with increasing population and poor economic<br />
performance in the developing countries, poverty, illiteracy, unemployment and<br />
social exclusion <strong>of</strong> the poor continued, and this led to the criticism and questioning<br />
<strong>of</strong> the trickle-down theory's assumptions.<br />
53
During this period, women and gender issues were largely ignored in development<br />
planning. As indicated, planned development focused predominantly on<br />
national economic growth and the individual's role was not given much thought.<br />
However, towards the end <strong>of</strong> the 1960s issues <strong>of</strong> class differentiation and socialisation<br />
within the family were given top priority. People involved in development<br />
practice faced different problems, as development programmes did not<br />
attempt to get local people to identify self-sustaining projects, but concentrated<br />
on the communities. However, this emphasis on the community obscured any<br />
distinctions between interests and concerns <strong>of</strong> richer or poorer, women and<br />
men. Development thinking drew heavily on the sexual division <strong>of</strong> labour within<br />
the family, whereby men were assumed to take care <strong>of</strong> the economic livelihood<br />
<strong>of</strong> the family and women to engage in tasks proper to the mother. Women were<br />
therefore not included in the development agenda: they were to a large extent<br />
viewed as passive beneficiaries in the development process and much emphasis<br />
was placed on their reproductive role.<br />
Development planners considered women's needs as merely family needs to<br />
be taken care <strong>of</strong> by men as assumed heads <strong>of</strong> households, who exercised<br />
benevolent authority over the family and control over resources (Young 1992).<br />
As a result, planners saw little wrong in liaising with local male-dominated<br />
organisations to disseminate information, inputs and equipment. The question<br />
<strong>of</strong> women's participation in supported economic activities appears never to<br />
have arisen. The dominant view was that women's participation in society was<br />
outside the economic mainstream; it was mainly restricted to activities for which<br />
women were stereotypically suited and to which they had been socialised:<br />
family, child welfare and household activities. Women were thus not integrated<br />
in the planners' model, as their work was not remunerated. Also, it was never<br />
contemplated that women would be an integral part and essential element <strong>of</strong><br />
development plans and implementation.<br />
By the end <strong>of</strong> the 1960s it was widely accepted that these approaches to<br />
development planning were not achieving their objectives. It became clear then<br />
that development involved more than just economic growth, and that economic<br />
growth alone could not bring about social equity and the necessary development<br />
in society. Therefore, it became obvious that development planners<br />
should adopt a broader but specified approach to development (Conyers & Hills<br />
1984).<br />
It was only in the early 1970s that development discussion focused on the<br />
majority <strong>of</strong> the human race: women, as highlighted by feminist research and<br />
54
women's organisations. Women's issues and development also became conceptually<br />
linked for the first time. Development planners shifted from viewing<br />
economic growth as the only development indicator and focused on equity,<br />
distribution, local capacity as well as cultural autonomy. The approach <strong>of</strong> the<br />
time was more people-centred and women's contribution to the family economy<br />
as well as family welfare was appreciated. The basic needs approach highlighted<br />
women's economic contribution, particularly in the poorest sectors <strong>of</strong><br />
society, and their needs as economic actors.<br />
The decade <strong>of</strong> the 1970s marked a new era <strong>of</strong> development programmes which<br />
established special units whose responsibilities were to promote and monitor<br />
progress among women as the disadvantaged group most affected by the<br />
majority <strong>of</strong> development activities. The LJN initiated concerns for gender relations<br />
in development in 1975 by declaring it women's year, which was then<br />
followed by the decade <strong>of</strong> the advancement <strong>of</strong> women, 1976±1985.<br />
The main objectives <strong>of</strong> the UN initiatives were to assess the extent to which<br />
women were being integrated into development plans and strategies and to find<br />
out why women seemed to be a neglected resource for development. These<br />
objectives were reinforced by the failure <strong>of</strong> the modernisation and economic<br />
growth theories <strong>of</strong> development in the developing countries during the previous<br />
two decades to bring about the anticipated development through trickle-down<br />
effects, and by their lack <strong>of</strong> consideration <strong>of</strong> the specific situations and roles <strong>of</strong><br />
women in development activities. There was also growing evidence that economic<br />
and social development efforts had not benefited women as much as<br />
they had benefited men. The problems <strong>of</strong> distribution and equity in the development<br />
process gained importance; for instance, in seeking better returns on<br />
their investments governments re-examined the roles <strong>of</strong> women and the gender<br />
notion in development. The UN initiatives further saw a consolidation <strong>of</strong> Women<br />
in Development (WID), and emphasis shifted from economic growth as a<br />
strategy for poverty alleviation and basic needs, to efficiency by utilising women<br />
more effectively by improving their productive capacity within the framework <strong>of</strong><br />
the market system (Young 1992).<br />
It was during this time that the WID group challenged the prevailing assumption<br />
that modernisation was equated with increasing gender equality. They asserted<br />
that capitalist development models imposed on Third World countries had exacerbated<br />
inequalities between men and women. They recognised that, in<br />
actual fact, women were active participants in the development process and<br />
provided a critical even though <strong>of</strong>ten unacknowledged contribution to economic<br />
55
growth. WID started from the basic assumption that economic strategies have<br />
frequently had a negative impact on women, hence they advocated women's<br />
integration into the development process through employment in the marketplace.<br />
They recognised the need for women's practical gender need to earn a<br />
livelihood. The WID approach also focused on issues <strong>of</strong> equity in both the public<br />
and private spheres <strong>of</strong> life and across socioeconomic groups. It identified origins<br />
<strong>of</strong> women's subordination not only in the context <strong>of</strong> the family, but also in<br />
relationships between men and women in the marketplace, and hence it placed<br />
considerable emphasis on economic independence as being synonymous with<br />
equity (Moser 1989).<br />
The UN initiatives and many other women's organisations <strong>of</strong> the time did not<br />
however bring about the much-sought change in development programmes to<br />
fully integrate women in development efforts. Most organisations and feminist<br />
researchers who advocated the change concentrated their efforts to a greater<br />
extent on women's integration in development activities, rather than on women's<br />
actual participation and recognition in various form <strong>of</strong> development activities.<br />
Also, the focus was much more on women as individuals and not as<br />
partners in development, hence the gender relation's notion in development<br />
was not articulated and specifically addressed. As argued by Ostergaard<br />
(1992), the WID concept <strong>of</strong> feminist researchers has to a large extent contributed<br />
to the marginalisation <strong>of</strong> women, in that it addressed women's issues as<br />
special problems in isolation and thus treated women as a particular species<br />
with inherited handicaps. As a result, at the end <strong>of</strong> the decade there was still<br />
considerable concern about the lack <strong>of</strong> understanding <strong>of</strong> gender relations in<br />
development, since development policies were still gender blind and biased<br />
against women. Even the antipoverty strategies that advocated increased<br />
participation <strong>of</strong> women in productive activities failed to provide equity in incomegenerating<br />
project activities. As stated by Moser (1989:165), `` anti-poverty income<br />
generating projects may provide employment for women, and thereby<br />
meet practical gender needs to augment income. But unless employment leads<br />
to greater autonomy, it does not meet strategic gender needs.'' Hence the UN<br />
(1980a) also indicates that, despite an increase in the overall labour force<br />
participation, women worked in the lowest paid and most sex-differentiated<br />
occupations, particularly in the service sector.<br />
Furthermore, the treatment and definitions <strong>of</strong> economic activity in planning were<br />
still market oriented, thus ignoring much <strong>of</strong> women's non-market and home<br />
based productive activities. Methodologically, the lack <strong>of</strong> a single indicator <strong>of</strong><br />
56
social status or progress <strong>of</strong> women and <strong>of</strong> baseline information about women's<br />
economic, social and political status meant that there were no standards<br />
against which success could be measured. Politically, the majority <strong>of</strong> development<br />
agencies were hostile to equity programmes precisely because <strong>of</strong> their<br />
intention to meet basic strategic gender needs, whose very success depended<br />
on an implicit redistribution <strong>of</strong> power (USAID 1978). Therefore, even though<br />
integration <strong>of</strong> women was the major slogan <strong>of</strong> the women's decade, at the end<br />
<strong>of</strong> the decade mainstreaming <strong>of</strong> gender in development planning emerged as it<br />
became apparent that despite the policies, mandates and strategies initiated<br />
during the decade; women's equal participation still remained a marginal issue<br />
within various development organisations (Jahan 1992).<br />
The decade <strong>of</strong> the 1990s started with momentous and unexpected changes that<br />
called for a reassessment <strong>of</strong> established thinking and old methods <strong>of</strong> development<br />
planning. Through a series <strong>of</strong> UN conferences from the 1992 conference<br />
on environment and development, through human rights in 1993,<br />
population and development in l994, social summit and women's conference in<br />
1995, and the habitat conference in 1996; specific thinking on gender and<br />
development gained ground. Also, the concept <strong>of</strong> WID became an institutionalised<br />
aspect <strong>of</strong> most international agencies, and many national governments<br />
have established programmes for women's advancement. The<br />
emphasis shifted from efficiency to empowerment and in some circles to democratisation.<br />
Following the decade <strong>of</strong> women and the series <strong>of</strong> various forums<br />
to bring women's issues to the forefront, women themselves have become<br />
more organised and are making demands for recognition, consultation and a<br />
greater degree <strong>of</strong> equality in diverse aspects <strong>of</strong> their lives with increasing<br />
persuasiveness and strength. Because <strong>of</strong> the growing strength <strong>of</strong> women's<br />
organisations throughout the world, Third World women began to make specific<br />
demands for women's voices to be heard in development decision making.<br />
Nevertheless, even though achievements have been marked by gains in terms<br />
<strong>of</strong> women's health, literacy, economic wellbeing and political participation;<br />
women still constitute the majority <strong>of</strong> the poor.<br />
WHY GENDER RELATIONS IN DEVELOPMENT PLANNING?<br />
Since 1970, there has been a proliferation <strong>of</strong> policy pronouncements, research<br />
programmes and publicity forums to promote awareness <strong>of</strong>, and concern for,<br />
the impact <strong>of</strong> development planning on women's lives. Thus feminist research<br />
abounds that women have <strong>of</strong>ten been the victims <strong>of</strong> development programmes<br />
57
ather than beneficiaries, and that many <strong>of</strong> these programmes that were assumed<br />
to benefit all people benefited men more and had negative impacts not<br />
only on women but on the entire community. The unintended marginalisation <strong>of</strong><br />
women in development planning has also led development agencies to rethink<br />
WID and to develop new approaches emphasising the need to mainstream<br />
women into development activities within a gendered framework, thus advocating<br />
a shift from women in development to a focus on gender relations in<br />
development efforts (Charlton & Ellen 1984).<br />
An emphasis on gender relations in development highlights the fact that work is<br />
gendered: that some tasks are seen as ``women's work'' which is demeaning to<br />
men; while others are seen as ``men's work'' and cannot be done by women.<br />
Focus on gender therefore encourages the questioning <strong>of</strong> the supposed unity and<br />
equal beneficiaries in development planning. The importance <strong>of</strong> gender in development<br />
stems from the fact that both men and women as human beings should<br />
be perceived as means and ends to any development activity, and therefore a<br />
gendered approach will ensure that men and women have equal access and<br />
control over resources. It is an implicit assumption that the effects <strong>of</strong> most development<br />
efforts are potentially beneficial to both men and women. In reality,<br />
quite <strong>of</strong>ten the advantages go to men in the form <strong>of</strong> increased earnings and all the<br />
disadvantages go to women in the form <strong>of</strong> increased and unremunerated workloads.<br />
Even where paid employment is <strong>of</strong>fered in development projects, childcare<br />
facilities are rarely provided and jobs are rarely placed in areas that are easily<br />
accessible from home. The projects <strong>of</strong>ten involve opportunity costs different for<br />
men and women; especially if women have children or ailing dependants.<br />
The strength <strong>of</strong> gender therefore lies in the insistence <strong>of</strong> mainstreaming women's<br />
issues and the belief that special sections in development planning<br />
should be run by women, not necessarily for women, but because the whole <strong>of</strong><br />
society needs transformation. In reality most development planners are men<br />
and they collect information and assess the development needs <strong>of</strong> men;<br />
therefore development programmes continue to be designed in line with the<br />
assumption that they will be carried out by men, whereas 80 percent <strong>of</strong> the work<br />
is actually done by women. Development planners are <strong>of</strong>ten convinced that if<br />
men as assumed heads <strong>of</strong> households take part in development activities,<br />
women will benefit passively. Little consideration if any is given to the control<br />
and distribution <strong>of</strong> resources within the household, even though it is likely that<br />
women and children are discriminated against in the distribution <strong>of</strong> resources<br />
(Venter 1994).<br />
58
According to Momsen (1991), development planners have thus preferred to<br />
define women's needs in terms <strong>of</strong> practical needs arising from the division <strong>of</strong><br />
labour by gender, instead <strong>of</strong> strategic gender needs that challenge this division<br />
<strong>of</strong> labour. This therefore reinforces the gender status quo and also discounts<br />
the reality that the gender status quo is actually based on unequal power relations<br />
deriving from the unequal distribution <strong>of</strong> resources, political representation<br />
and organisational strength. Even though planners are aware <strong>of</strong><br />
these aspects <strong>of</strong> women's subordination, they find it safer and more expedient<br />
to focus on the needs that will not threaten men's power and privileges in<br />
society. Hence they prefer to overlook women's basic needs that arise from<br />
their subordinate position in society and the needs that require a radical<br />
transformation in interpersonal relations that will allow women greater power<br />
over their lives and in the decision-making process. A gender conceptual framework<br />
in development should therefore emphasise that in actual fact women<br />
are incorporated in the development process, but in very specific ways; that a<br />
focus on women alone is inadequate to understand the opportunities for<br />
change; that women are not a homogeneous category but are divided by class,<br />
colour and creed ± that any analysis <strong>of</strong> social organisation and social process<br />
has to take into account the structure and dynamics <strong>of</strong> gender relations; that the<br />
totality <strong>of</strong> women's and men's lives has to be the focus <strong>of</strong> analysis, not merely<br />
their productive or reproductive activities; and lastly that women are not passive<br />
or marginal but active participants in development activities.<br />
Mainstreaming a gender perspective in development planning should involve<br />
the process <strong>of</strong> assessing the implications for women and men <strong>of</strong> any planned<br />
action, including legislation, policies or programmes in all areas and at all levels.<br />
A gendered perspective ensures that women's and men's concerns and experiences<br />
are an integral dimension <strong>of</strong> the design, implementation, monitoring<br />
and evaluation <strong>of</strong> policies and programmes in all political, economic and societal<br />
spheres so that both men and women benefit equally and inequality is not<br />
perpetuated.<br />
CHALLENGES OF DEVELOPMENT PLANNERS IN THE 21st<br />
CENTURY<br />
As indicated earlier, in the first decades after the Second World War the pursuit<br />
<strong>of</strong> economic development was reflected in the almost universal acceptance <strong>of</strong><br />
development planning as the surest and most direct route to economic progress.<br />
However, recently people in the developing countries have started<br />
59
questioning the advisability and desirability <strong>of</strong> formulating and implementing<br />
national development plans.<br />
In the first decades after the Second World War, the pursuit <strong>of</strong> economic development<br />
was reflected in the almost universal acceptance <strong>of</strong> development<br />
planning as the surest and most direct route to economic progress. People in<br />
the developing countries have recently started questioning the advisability and<br />
desirability <strong>of</strong> formulating and implementing national development plans, but<br />
even though development agencies and Third World governments are now<br />
trying to formulate and implement new policies on women's development, the<br />
success <strong>of</strong> these policies largely depends on increased gender awareness<br />
among development personnel. Todaro (1994:565) points out that in spite <strong>of</strong><br />
this new awareness, development planning has become a way <strong>of</strong> life in government<br />
ministries and that every five years development plans are paraded<br />
with great fanfare.<br />
Ostergaard (1992) argues that, even today, the target groups for development<br />
efforts are still identified as genderless categories such as ``farmers'' or ``urban<br />
poor''. In the minds <strong>of</strong> planners these groups are assumed to be male dominated.<br />
Planners must therefore realise that development goals will only be<br />
reached by securing the active involvement <strong>of</strong> women as well as men, and by<br />
bringing women into the mainstream <strong>of</strong> economic development; so that each<br />
gender plays its own important role in the process.<br />
As stated by Young (1992), involving women at all levels <strong>of</strong> development<br />
thinking, planning and implementation will make a world <strong>of</strong> difference, not<br />
merely to women but to the capacity <strong>of</strong> society to envisage and carry out<br />
planned social change. Development planners are therefore faced with the task<br />
<strong>of</strong> re-examining social structures, institutions and power relations among different<br />
groups in society. This requires a degree <strong>of</strong> commitment to structural<br />
change and power shifts ± hence the need for planners to fully understand and<br />
recognise the links between women's subordination, continuing poverty, population<br />
crisis and unsustainable forms <strong>of</strong> economic organisation.<br />
Young (1997) further argues that bringing women to centre stage will require<br />
pr<strong>of</strong>ound changes in the way societies conceive <strong>of</strong> relations between the<br />
genders: it will require the dismantling <strong>of</strong> centuries-old structures <strong>of</strong> thought and<br />
practice. Therefore, in mainstreaming gender in development the focus should<br />
not be on women per se, but on men and women and their relations in the<br />
development process. Hence the unit <strong>of</strong> analysis should be shifted from the<br />
60
household as a homogeneous decision-making unit to the individual, so that the<br />
needs <strong>of</strong> men and women may be highlighted and dealt with in a manner that<br />
will not discriminate against either sex, but will be beneficial to all.<br />
Even though it may take time to mainstream gender in development planning, it<br />
has become increasingly clear over the past decades that women are a tremendous<br />
social resource which societies can no longer afford to undervalue or<br />
under-use ± hence the need to treat women as partners in development rather<br />
than resources in the overall development processes. Planners have a great<br />
responsibility to listen to women, respond to their articulated needs, involve<br />
them in planning and evaluation, and to build their vision into planning strategies.<br />
It is obvious therefore that development planners should be gender planners.<br />
They should adopt a gender perspective which involves the process <strong>of</strong> assessing<br />
the implications for both women and men <strong>of</strong> any planned action, including<br />
legislation, policies or programmes, in all areas and at all levels.<br />
Planners should ensure that women's and men's concerns and experiences are<br />
an integral dimension <strong>of</strong> the design, implementation, monitoring and evaluation<br />
<strong>of</strong> policies and programmes in all political, economic and societal spheres. The<br />
following questions have to be asked in order to assess the success <strong>of</strong> any<br />
planned action: Have both men and women been consulted equally? What is<br />
the sex ratio <strong>of</strong> people involved in the decision-making process? What is the<br />
likely impact on gender equality goals? (Moser 1989).<br />
Gianotten (1994:12) recommends that certain activities should be carried out<br />
before the implementation <strong>of</strong> programmes: firstly, the collection <strong>of</strong> baseline data<br />
such as gender pr<strong>of</strong>iles; and secondly screening with respect to potential effects.<br />
This recommendation, in conjunction with the concepts <strong>of</strong> autonomy and<br />
empowerment <strong>of</strong> women, clearly shows the necessity <strong>of</strong> developing a methodology<br />
which could serve as a planning instrument and perhaps give an indication<br />
<strong>of</strong> the potential impact <strong>of</strong> proposed development projects and<br />
programmes on gender relations within a given society.<br />
CONCLUSION<br />
As has been illustrated, a need for gender awareness in development efforts<br />
was recognised some 20 years ago when planners realised that economic<br />
growth and modernisation could not be achieved without the recognition and<br />
participation <strong>of</strong> both men and women in the development process. When<br />
61
gender differences are overlooked in the planning process, development initiatives<br />
are unlikely to respond to women's needs and may have negative<br />
consequences for them. There is some evidence to the fact that development<br />
strategies based solely on macroeconomic theories have failed to solve problems<br />
<strong>of</strong> poverty in developing countries. Moreover, these strategies have had<br />
the unforseen side effects <strong>of</strong> making the poor and underprivileged even poorer.<br />
A gendered perspective to development should therefore be one in which<br />
women's knowledge, experiences and perceptions are given validity and allowed<br />
to come to the fore in analysing and presenting issues. This perspective<br />
should ensure that changes occurring in society ± planned or unplanned ± are<br />
viewed critically, taking into consideration that people are essential elements in<br />
all development activities.<br />
BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />
Allan, J & Thomas, A 1992. Poverty and development in the 1990s. Oxford: Oxford<br />
<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />
Anand, A 1992. Women in the Third World redefine their environment. London: ZED.<br />
Boserup, E 1970. Women's role in economic development. New York: St Martin's.<br />
Charlton, M & Ellen, S 1984. Women in Third World development. Boulder, Colo:<br />
Westview.<br />
Conyers, D & Hills, P 1984. An introduction to development planning in the Third World.<br />
New York: Wiley.<br />
Gianotten, V 1994. Assessing the gender impact <strong>of</strong> development projects: case studies<br />
from Bolivia, Burkina Faso and India. London: Intermediate Technology.<br />
Jahan, R 1992. Mainstreaming women in development in different settings. Bangladesh:<br />
Dhaka <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />
Longwe, S 1991. Gender awareness: the missing element in the Third World development<br />
project, in Changing Perceptions: Writings on Gender and Development,<br />
edited by T Wallace. Oxford: Oxfam.<br />
Moser, C 1989. Gender planning in Third World Countries: meeting practical and strategic<br />
gender needs. World Development 17(11):1799±1825.<br />
Momsen, J 1991. Women and development in the Third World. London: Routledge.<br />
Ostergaard, L 1992. Gender and development: a practical guide. London: Routledge.<br />
Todaro, M P 1994. Economic development. 5th edition. London: Longman.<br />
UNESCO 1986. Socio-economic analysis and planning: critical choices <strong>of</strong> methodologies.<br />
Paris.<br />
United Nations 1980a. World Conference <strong>of</strong> the UN Decade <strong>of</strong> Women: Equality, Development<br />
and Peace (Copenhagen). New York.<br />
USAID 1978. Report on women in development. Washington DC: USAID Office <strong>of</strong><br />
Women in Development.<br />
62
Venter, M 1994. Prospects for progress: critical choices for <strong>South</strong>ern <strong>Africa</strong>. Cape Town:<br />
Maskew Miller Longman.<br />
Young, K 1993. Planning development with women: making a world <strong>of</strong> difference.<br />
London: Macmillan.<br />
Young, K 1997. Planning from a gender perspective: making a world <strong>of</strong> a difference, in<br />
7he women, gender and development reader, edited by D Visvanathan. London:<br />
ZED.<br />
63
On the relationship between<br />
participatory research and<br />
participatory development<br />
Naude Malan<br />
ABSTRACT<br />
The connections between participatory development and participatory research<br />
are examined in this article. It is argued that participation in research<br />
is not sufficient to bring about participatory development. This line <strong>of</strong> reasoning<br />
is pursued to make the point that the social and political context<br />
determines whether the normative claims <strong>of</strong> participatory development are<br />
attainable through a development intervention. The article then examines<br />
those aspects <strong>of</strong> development in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> that would have a decisive<br />
influence on the outcomes <strong>of</strong> participatory intervention, such as neoliberal<br />
policy choices, changes in the local government dispensation, the role <strong>of</strong><br />
traditional authorities and the state <strong>of</strong> civil society in the country. The article<br />
concludes that these, and other elements <strong>of</strong> the social context, need to be<br />
aligned with participatory development interventions for the claims <strong>of</strong> participation<br />
to become feasible.<br />
INTRODUCTION<br />
Participation is <strong>of</strong>ten seen by its proponents as fundamental to sound development<br />
policy, strategy, practice and research. Within the paradigm <strong>of</strong> participation,<br />
two distinct but possibly related elements are present: participation in<br />
research, and participation in development. Participation is <strong>of</strong>ten presented as<br />
necessary for development to be appropriate to those who will be involved in it.<br />
Similarly, participation is presented as necessary for development research to<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>nus <strong>30</strong>(2)2000 64
address and reveal the plight <strong>of</strong> the most needy. This article will take a critical<br />
look at the participatory development paradigm by examining the conditions<br />
under which participatory research interventions could lead to participatory<br />
development. The argument is based on the premise that participatory research<br />
will not necessarily lead to participatory development. This article will try to point<br />
out those aspects <strong>of</strong> the social context which could be conducive to participatory<br />
research crossing the threshold to participatory development. In doing so, I<br />
would like to move away from a discussion <strong>of</strong> the implementation <strong>of</strong> these<br />
methodologies, and examine those elements in the social context that need to<br />
be aligned to the wider participatory project for it to become feasible.<br />
My argument, which will be substantiated in the body <strong>of</strong> the article, is structured<br />
as follows: I will first establish that there is not necessarily a connection between<br />
participatory research and participatory development. It is easy to conflate<br />
the two elements, with the result that mere participation in research, or<br />
participation in research techniques, is seen as an adequate form <strong>of</strong> involvement<br />
for people in development projects. A development intervention making<br />
use <strong>of</strong> participatory research would not necessarily lead to participatory development.<br />
Similarly, development interventions that do not attempt to structure<br />
participation strategically cannot claim to be participatory. The results <strong>of</strong> participatory<br />
research will not be incorporated in a development project and the<br />
quality <strong>of</strong> the lives <strong>of</strong> the people involved will not be affected, unless certain<br />
conditions are met. The crux <strong>of</strong> my argument is that these factors lie outside the<br />
domain <strong>of</strong> the development project. These factors include an institutional dimension<br />
represented by the implementing agency responsible for development;<br />
a methodological dimension represented by the execution <strong>of</strong> research; and a<br />
social dimension represented by the local politics <strong>of</strong> the area in which the<br />
project will be implemented. I suggest that the problems <strong>of</strong> participatory development<br />
may be overcome by interpreting them as problems <strong>of</strong> civil society.<br />
This forces us to consider the hypothesis that participation in (governmental)<br />
development projects could have important implications for associative behaviour<br />
within civil society, which could in turn have negative implications for the<br />
long-term project <strong>of</strong> social change.<br />
PARTICIPATORY RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT<br />
The belief that local people are more aware than outside researchers <strong>of</strong> local<br />
idiosyncrasies, such as climate, environment, needs that are important for<br />
development projects and similar interventions, is fundamental to the idea <strong>of</strong><br />
65
participatory development and research. This belief in the capabilities <strong>of</strong> beneficiaries<br />
leads to the idea that people could be instrumental in the design <strong>of</strong><br />
their own development interventions. Concurrent with this, certain researchers<br />
began experimenting with using local people in research for development<br />
projects, frequently without the knowledge <strong>of</strong> development agencies. It became<br />
clear that certain information could be supplied by local people very quickly and<br />
more accurately than by orthodox social research for development projects.<br />
This considerably decreased the costs and effort <strong>of</strong> research for development<br />
projects. Once this capability was recognised, researchers began to structure<br />
these contributions to the intended project around certain techniques and<br />
methods. Instead <strong>of</strong> undertaking, say, an expensive laboratory analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />
soils present at a project site, local people could evaluate the soils together with<br />
the researcher using specific techniques, at times incorporating indigenous<br />
concepts and practices into the results and subsequent project design. In most<br />
instances local knowledge was deemed to be as good as scientific knowledge.<br />
The premise was that, because local people would be the ultimate beneficiaries<br />
<strong>of</strong> the project, their concepts and understanding <strong>of</strong> the area should be sufficient<br />
and would be particularly relevant to the specific situation. The idea was systematically<br />
developed that, armed with the right knowledge and backup, local<br />
people could be the researchers, initiators and managers <strong>of</strong> their own development<br />
projects. That is the classic conception <strong>of</strong> participatory development<br />
and research. The prime example in this genre is the expatriate researcher<br />
who, when told <strong>of</strong> research in progress, is reminded that ``You do not need to<br />
come''.<br />
Participatory research as a concept is not new; some people claim that it has<br />
been used since the 1940s (Selener 1997). The paradigm <strong>of</strong> participatory research<br />
has varied origins: Selener (1997) distinguishes four different sources.<br />
According to him, Participatory Action Research (somewhat different from the<br />
varieties discussed in this article) originated from Community Development,<br />
Action Research in Organisations, Action Research in Education and, <strong>of</strong><br />
course, from Farmer Participatory Research. Such diverse origins explain the<br />
flexibility and variety <strong>of</strong> participatory research. An important element <strong>of</strong> its origin<br />
is social researchers' dissatisfaction with orthodox methods <strong>of</strong> research for<br />
development (see Chambers 1991). Their criticism has been partly responsible<br />
for the present proliferation <strong>of</strong> methods. On all these counts, the use <strong>of</strong> participatory<br />
research for development is a liberating experience, both for researchers<br />
and participants (cf Martin 1994).<br />
66
Participatory research today is a multifaceted approach to the study <strong>of</strong> development.<br />
Contemporary techniques have been developed primarily by practitioners<br />
(Chambers 1994b:1262; Grimble & Wellard 1997:187). Many different<br />
varieties, each suited to a particular application, form part <strong>of</strong> an extensive repertoire<br />
<strong>of</strong> techniques available to development workers and researchers.<br />
Some <strong>of</strong> the methodologies in which participation plays a crucial role are: action<br />
research (Fals-Borda 1981; Fals-Borda & Rahman 1991; Selener 1997), Participatory<br />
Rural Appraisal or ``PRA'' (Chambers 1994 a,b,c) (also referred to as<br />
``PLA'' ± Participatory Learning and Action) and Farming Systems Research<br />
(Haverkort et al 1991). They are useful for academic inquiry (cf Scoones et al<br />
1996; Scoones 1997; Mearns 1996; Grimble & Wellard 1997; Martin & Sherington<br />
1997); are simple enough for anyone to use (see Mosse 1994:524±526;<br />
Chambers 1991; 1994c); and ideally, would reveal data that would decisively<br />
influence the design <strong>of</strong> a project (see Chambers 1994a:533; Leurs 1996; Martin<br />
& Sherington 1997).<br />
PARADOXES OF PARTICIPATION<br />
Participatory research undoubtedly has noble qualities, and the word ``participation''<br />
is used in most contemporary discussions <strong>of</strong> empowerment. However,<br />
participation is also used as a development strategy in many organisations that<br />
are unlikely to consider the interests <strong>of</strong> the ``target group'' exclusively. Grimble<br />
and Wellard (1997:184) equate Participatory Rural Appraisal (PRA) or Rapid<br />
Rural Appraisal (RRA) with the development strategy used by the World Bank<br />
and the Overseas Development Administration (ODA) <strong>of</strong> the United Kingdom.<br />
The ambivalent nature <strong>of</strong> the paradigm <strong>of</strong> participatory research is particularly<br />
important in evaluating the application <strong>of</strong> these techniques in development aid<br />
programmes (see Grimble & Wellard 1997; Oakley 1995). These ``social methodologies''<br />
(Cernea 1987) come into their own in the context <strong>of</strong> a development<br />
project and are concerned with ``the practicalities <strong>of</strong> consensus building and<br />
developing a workable project'' (Grimble & Wellard 1997:186). Perhaps these<br />
techniques are used for instrumental, rather than for emancipatory reasons.<br />
This disjuncture between the interests <strong>of</strong> the participants and the implementing<br />
agency becomes even more acute when some <strong>of</strong> the origins <strong>of</strong> these methodologies<br />
are examined. Biggs and Smith (1998) trace the origins <strong>of</strong> participatory<br />
methodology, specifically Rapid Rural Appraisal (RRA), through case<br />
studies. According to them, the successful use <strong>of</strong> these methods depends on<br />
the possibility <strong>of</strong> ``coalition building'' between the people involved and other key<br />
67
stakeholders. These coalitions were built behind the scenes, through lobbying<br />
by influential individuals (Biggs & Smith 1998:246). Unfortunately, they do not<br />
discuss the problem <strong>of</strong> patronage. According to them the crucial factor in the<br />
success <strong>of</strong> these methodologies is not the kind <strong>of</strong> participation by beneficiaries,<br />
but rather the ``social and political context <strong>of</strong> the methods' application''<br />
(1998:241). In this case, what participation can or cannot accomplish would<br />
depend on the political economy <strong>of</strong> development aid. From this discussion it is<br />
clear that participatory research, and by implication development interventions<br />
in which participation is strategically structured, will not necessarily lead to the<br />
kind <strong>of</strong> development that is devoted to the interests <strong>of</strong> the participants. Participation<br />
in a development project could serve interests other than those <strong>of</strong> the<br />
beneficiaries. I would suggest that we should consider the kind <strong>of</strong> participation<br />
by beneficiaries as much as the kind <strong>of</strong> development project itself. In order to do<br />
this, we have to analyse the contemporary political economy, for example, the<br />
type <strong>of</strong> macroeconomic policy choices made, interest groups relevant to the<br />
project, and their impact on activity at local level.<br />
This ambivalence is highlighted by Selener (1997:203±204), when he distinguishes<br />
between technical and political forms <strong>of</strong> participatory research. Participation<br />
as a technical intervention is:<br />
[a] tactic for involving people in practical activities in the process <strong>of</strong> problem<br />
definition, data collection, data analysis and implementation <strong>of</strong> results ...<br />
Participation <strong>of</strong> a technical nature can be manipulated by power holders to<br />
fulfil their own needs and thus may not promote empowerment or social<br />
change (Selener 1997:203±204).<br />
Selener continues:<br />
Participation <strong>of</strong> a political nature means acquiring power and taking greater<br />
control <strong>of</strong> a situation by increasing options for action, autonomy and reflection,<br />
especially through the development and strengthening <strong>of</strong> institutions<br />
(1997:204; his emphasis).<br />
Participation, in an ideal sense, is a political strategy that promotes the interests<br />
<strong>of</strong> participants in development over those who implement projects. The political<br />
nature <strong>of</strong> participation, however, could also serve as a veil behind which power<br />
could be consolidated and used more effectively (Rahnema 1993).<br />
When we postulate the social context as instrumental to whether participatory<br />
research leads to participatory development and (possibly) positive social<br />
68
change, the problems underlying development change fundamentally. It forces<br />
us to see the social element as determining the direction <strong>of</strong> development, and<br />
not development as the motive force behind social change. In many ways this is<br />
a classic debate. It is ideological to suppose that only development and development<br />
projects would change our social reality. The development project<br />
may all too easily become subservient to the powers that be, or development<br />
may follow contemporary fashions, <strong>of</strong> which ``participation'' is the most prominent<br />
example. The conflation <strong>of</strong> participatory development and participatory<br />
research is a variation on this fallacy. Participation was suggested as a solution<br />
to development problems decades ago (cf Lele 1975:62±78), but has only recently<br />
been examined more rigorously (Mannikutti 1997; Uph<strong>of</strong> et al 1990). The<br />
paradigm is badly in need <strong>of</strong> critical scrutiny.<br />
Clearly, the use <strong>of</strong> participatory research does not guarantee social change<br />
associated with the ``development and strengthening <strong>of</strong> institutions'' (Selener<br />
1997:204). The strength <strong>of</strong> participatory research lies in its ability to engineer an<br />
intervention that suits local circumstances. This ability could, however, depreciate<br />
the necessity <strong>of</strong> deeper social change. Social change needs to be<br />
premised upon local circumstances. This is not only a moral, but also an economic<br />
imperative as any area has some form <strong>of</strong> comparative advantage over<br />
others. However, this same point <strong>of</strong> entry that legitimises participation can also<br />
make such research susceptible to local influences that are less benign and<br />
sometimes destructive (cf Mayoux 1995; Mosse 1994). An appreciation <strong>of</strong> local<br />
elements as a foundation for development is needed, but also an understanding<br />
that this local nature <strong>of</strong> development is embedded in a wider context, and that<br />
this wider context could undo any local gains. In order to apply this to participatory<br />
development, we will examine the institutional, the methodological and<br />
the social dimensions <strong>of</strong> development in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>.<br />
THE MULTIPLE DIMENSIONS OF PARTICIPATORY<br />
DEVELOPMENT<br />
The previous discussion implies that participatory research and development<br />
must be combined with other aspects <strong>of</strong> intervention to lead to positive social<br />
change. Creating the right institutional environment is one aspect <strong>of</strong> this (Martin<br />
& Sherington 1997; Bunders & Broerse 1991). The policy choices any organisation<br />
or government makes are crucial in this regard. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, and the<br />
<strong>South</strong> in general, are at present caught in a hegemony <strong>of</strong> neoliberal policy.<br />
Consequently, the scope for participation in policy formulation in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong><br />
69
seems limited at present, especially for rural people (see Blake 1998; Maganya<br />
1996). It is inconceivable that a government department or a major parastatal<br />
development organisation would be able to go against the grain <strong>of</strong> these<br />
macroeconomic policy choices.<br />
Besides, the organisational culture <strong>of</strong> a development agency will have to go<br />
through numerous institutional and ideological changes in order to be able to<br />
implement radical participatory development programmes. The fact that major<br />
international institutions involved in development subscribe to the participatory<br />
discourse, and uphold the neoliberal paradigm as well, makes one wonder<br />
about the authenticity <strong>of</strong> participatory development.<br />
In <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> the neoliberal hegemony on policy alternatives is represented by<br />
the Growth, Employment and Redistribution (GEAR) programme. The Reconstruction<br />
and Development Programme (RDP) is usually presented as an<br />
alternative to GEAR. What is important for participatory development is how<br />
these two opposites are reconciled in Government policy, and the ways in which<br />
local-level participation may lead to shifts between the RDP and GEAR paradigms.<br />
Even within a neoliberal environment, government departments still<br />
have a responsibility to take heed <strong>of</strong> the alternatives that could emanate from<br />
the participation <strong>of</strong> people in their development projects. The fact that the RDP<br />
is well known at local level throughout the country makes it almost impossible to<br />
implement development projects without some form <strong>of</strong> community cooperation.<br />
If participation in this regard leads to more efficient projects, the condition <strong>of</strong><br />
efficiency will at least be satisfied. Certain other conditions that are part <strong>of</strong><br />
demand-led development, like limited local decision making, will also be satisfied.<br />
In certain instances, where the particular service that is delivered is<br />
relatively uncontroversial, like water, these trade-<strong>of</strong>fs do not amount to much. In<br />
other instances, like agricultural technology development, where the links between<br />
livelihoods and technology adoption are very controversial, these trade<strong>of</strong>fs<br />
could have pr<strong>of</strong>ound implications for the people involved. We still need to<br />
explore the links between our development priorities and their relationship with<br />
different policy alternatives. Then we will be in a position to evaluate how the<br />
neoliberal policy choices we have made will impact on certain segments <strong>of</strong> the<br />
<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n population.<br />
The object <strong>of</strong> participatory development is to allow beneficiaries to control development.<br />
This does not only concern the management <strong>of</strong> development projects,<br />
but also the execution <strong>of</strong> research. When people other than the ``target<br />
group'' are in control, development could be shaped to suit them. The local-level<br />
70
power play in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n communities on the topic <strong>of</strong> ``development'' could<br />
create the opportunity for influential individuals to influence workshops and<br />
other methods <strong>of</strong> participatory research decisively. Because we would want the<br />
community to control development, we would be unaware <strong>of</strong> the dynamics and<br />
rationale underlying decisions and actions taken. This makes it difficult to know<br />
when the results <strong>of</strong> participatory research are reliable and valid. The epistemology<br />
<strong>of</strong> participatory research demands that the methodological be subservient<br />
to the political. The emphasis on the political, however, could also allow<br />
individuals outside the ``target group,'' or interests outside those <strong>of</strong> the community,<br />
to control research. In this way doubt is cast on the methodological<br />
rigour employed in participatory research, which makes it a less lucrative alternative<br />
to orthodox social research.<br />
Participatory development in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, besides being affected by the concerns<br />
raised earlier, will be pr<strong>of</strong>oundly affected by local-level authority, which<br />
includes traditional leaders and local authorities. It may easily be argued that<br />
traditional leaders constitute one <strong>of</strong> the most crucial, if not overlooked, aspects<br />
<strong>of</strong> rural development in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. However, their role in development is not<br />
clear at the moment. Making a commitment to helping the poorest would not<br />
necessarily intrude upon their authority. However, making a commitment<br />
against the better <strong>of</strong>f could well do this. Allowing women access and control<br />
over land would most probably lead to conflict: many men control their own<br />
piece <strong>of</strong> land, and this will diminish the chances <strong>of</strong> more men gaining land. On<br />
the other hand, traditional leaders do have a responsibility toward their communities,<br />
and it is inconceivable that they would do something that goes against<br />
the wishes <strong>of</strong> the majority <strong>of</strong> their ``subjects.'' Opponents <strong>of</strong> traditional authority<br />
structures <strong>of</strong>ten accuse them <strong>of</strong> playing the role <strong>of</strong> gatekeepers, as they have<br />
considerable influence over rural life. However, they could be a most important<br />
ally in a market-driven political economy.<br />
Individual headmen and tribal councils could be more or less sympathetic to the<br />
empowerment <strong>of</strong> target groups such as small farmers. Close cooperation and<br />
strategic trade-<strong>of</strong>fs with individual traditional authorities could create the possibility<br />
<strong>of</strong> a development project under the control <strong>of</strong> the participants. The peculiarity<br />
<strong>of</strong> this situation is that the possibility <strong>of</strong> establishing a participatory<br />
development project would depend more on the willingness <strong>of</strong> individual traditional<br />
leaders to grant access to land, than on national policy on traditional<br />
authority.<br />
Local Government in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> has been placed on a unique footing com-<br />
71
pared to the rest <strong>of</strong> the world (Harris 1999). The process <strong>of</strong> restructuring local<br />
government in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> as developmental local government has only just<br />
started. The efficacy <strong>of</strong> participatory interventions in development would depend<br />
greatly on the demarcation <strong>of</strong> local government boundaries. The first<br />
priority would <strong>of</strong> course be that these newly constituted municipal structures do<br />
have the capacity to deliver services to their populations. The question that<br />
concerns us here, is whether service delivery is a developmental category<br />
sufficiently sophisticated and flexible to accommodate specific and distinctive<br />
needs. If participatory development is premised upon local idiosyncrasies, what<br />
scope is there for variation on the themes <strong>of</strong> sewerage, water, electricity and<br />
roads?<br />
Other factors could also be taken into consideration. ``Local Economic Development''<br />
is one way in which local authorities can ``bend'' the neoliberal development<br />
paradigm so that their constituent populations receive a greater<br />
share <strong>of</strong> the economic pie. The results <strong>of</strong> such efforts do not always seem to<br />
fulfil the promise <strong>of</strong> a participatory or a redistributive ideology (see Maharaj &<br />
Rambali 1998). Local Economic Development seems to be more subservient to<br />
broader currents that shape our society than to local level interests. Therefore,<br />
it is doubtful whether such a developmental strategy could satisfy the demands<br />
<strong>of</strong> the participatory ideology.<br />
The change in demarcation <strong>of</strong> local government boundaries is bound to have an<br />
effect on people and their organisation that is not necessarily covered by the<br />
participatory paradigm. Local level organisations are <strong>of</strong>ten premised against<br />
and/or upon cooperation with local government or traditional authorities. The<br />
new demarcation <strong>of</strong> local authority areas would have an effect on civil society at<br />
local level. Participatory interventions would have a pr<strong>of</strong>ound effect on the way<br />
these organisations function. The lack <strong>of</strong> rigorous discussion in the literature on<br />
the relationship between civil society and social movements and development<br />
is a cause for concern (but see Lindberg & Sverrison 1997). This very important<br />
aspect <strong>of</strong> associational life, on which the obsession with the ``target group''<br />
directly intrudes, could be negatively or positively affected by participatory intervention.<br />
The point needs to be made that there should be room for forms <strong>of</strong><br />
associational life other than the development committee to make an impact on<br />
developmental choices. Other forms <strong>of</strong> civil society and social movements, not<br />
directly related to development, need to be given room to function, as they<br />
ultimately contribute to the virility <strong>of</strong> civil society in general. An autonomous and<br />
independent civil society is crucial for long-term social change (Young 1994).<br />
72
The long-term health <strong>of</strong> civil society and these organisations is what participatory<br />
development should be about, and not maximising the material gains<br />
from development projects.<br />
CONCLUSION<br />
Agencies which strive to implement participatory development should realise<br />
that more is at stake than participatory needs assessments. It is quite possible<br />
that they should engage in advocacy at higher levels in order to bring about the<br />
social changes needed for successful participatory development. These<br />
changes will most probably not occur with participatory research and development<br />
on their own. The notion <strong>of</strong> ``coalition building'' alluded to earlier points<br />
to the fact that an influential individual in a development organisation would<br />
have to play the role <strong>of</strong> benevolent gatekeeper. The paradox is that the sense <strong>of</strong><br />
conscience <strong>of</strong> such a person will have to be greater than the sense <strong>of</strong> accountability<br />
<strong>of</strong> his or her organisation.<br />
We could argue that participatory development could lead to appropriate development<br />
interventions, because participation gives a point <strong>of</strong> entry to the<br />
social context. It is, however, not clear whether this ability <strong>of</strong> participatory research<br />
and development is critical. Will it necessarily challenge the status quo?<br />
For instance, in many parts <strong>of</strong> rural <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, rainfed farming is a common<br />
agricultural strategy. There has to be a reason for this. Given the widespread<br />
poverty, lack <strong>of</strong> capital, landlessness and shortage <strong>of</strong> labour characteristic <strong>of</strong><br />
rural <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> (see Marcus et al 1996; Lipton, Ellis & Lipton 1996), is rainfed<br />
farming not a very appropriate agricultural strategy? Without fundamental<br />
change to these aspects <strong>of</strong> rural life, is it possible to implement true ``participatory<br />
development''? Participatory research and development is an excellent<br />
strategy for local or community-based development. However, this local focus<br />
might be completely inappropriate for dealing with structural inequalities such<br />
as the landlessness <strong>of</strong> rural people. Some issues have to be addressed and<br />
changed at the national and sometimes international level, for participation to<br />
become a viable development strategy.<br />
These comments seem very similar to the ``traditional'' concerns <strong>of</strong> development.<br />
The beauty <strong>of</strong> the participatory development paradigm is that it points to<br />
the necessity <strong>of</strong> a much more radical transformation in these traditional concerns<br />
than we have envisaged up to now. Participation is only one part <strong>of</strong> the<br />
participatory development project. This is its true value: because the obstacles<br />
73
to attaining empowerment are still the same, overcoming them will have to be<br />
done all the more radically.<br />
BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />
Blake, M 1998. Are the poor being heard? The implications <strong>of</strong> the government's shift in<br />
economic policy for reducing poverty in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, in Creating action space: the<br />
challenge <strong>of</strong> poverty and democracy in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, edited by C Baberton, M<br />
Blake & H Kotze . Cape Town: IDASA & David Phillip.<br />
Biggs, S & Smith, G 1998. Beyond methodologies: coalition-building for participatory<br />
technology development. World Development 26(2):239±48.<br />
Bunders, J F G & Broerse, J E W 1991. Appropriate biotechnology in small-scale agriculture:<br />
how to reorient research and development. Wallingford: CAB International.<br />
Cernea, M M 1987. The `production' <strong>of</strong> a social methodology, in Applied anthropology in<br />
America, 2nd edition, edited by E M Eddy & W L Partridge. New York: Columbia<br />
<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />
Chambers, R 1991. Shortcut and participatory methods for gaining social information for<br />
projects, in Putting people first: sociological variables in rural development, 2nd<br />
edition, edited by M M Cernea. Washington, DC: International Bank for Reconstruction<br />
and Development.<br />
Chambers, R 1994a. The origins and practice <strong>of</strong> participatory rural appraisal. World<br />
Development 22(7).<br />
Chambers, R 1994b. Participatory Rural Appraisal (PRA): analysis <strong>of</strong> experience. World<br />
Development 22(9).<br />
Chambers, R 1994c. Participatory Rural Appraisal (PRA): challenges, potentials and<br />
paradigm. World Development 22(10).<br />
Fals-Borda, O 1981. The challenge <strong>of</strong> Action Research. Development Seeds <strong>of</strong> Change<br />
1:55±61.<br />
Fals-Borda, O & Rahman, M A (eds) 1991. Action and knowledge: breaking the<br />
monopoly with Participatory Action-Research. New York: Apex.<br />
Grimble, R & Wellard, K 1997. Stakeholder methodologies in natural resource management:<br />
a review <strong>of</strong> principles, contexts, experiences and opportunities. Agricultural<br />
Systems 55(2):173±93.<br />
Harris, J C 1999. The challenge <strong>of</strong> local government delivery. Development <strong>South</strong>ern<br />
<strong>Africa</strong> 16(1):183±193.<br />
Haverkort, B, van der Kamp, J & Waters-Bayer, A (eds) 1991. Joining farmers' experiments<br />
experiences in participatory technology development. London: Intermediate<br />
Technology Publications.<br />
Lele, U 1975. The design <strong>of</strong> rural development: lessons from <strong>Africa</strong>. Baltimore: Johns<br />
Hopkins <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />
Leurs, R 1996. Current challenges facing Participatory Rural Appraisal. Public Administration<br />
and Development 16.<br />
74
Lindberg, S & Sverrisson, A 1997. Social movements in development: the challenge <strong>of</strong><br />
globalization and democratization. London: Macmillan.<br />
Lipton, M, Ellis, F & Lipton, M (eds) 1996. Land labour and livelihoods in rural <strong>South</strong><br />
<strong>Africa</strong>, vol 2: KwaZulu-Natal and <strong>No</strong>rthern Province. Durban: Indicator.<br />
Maganya, E 1996. The contemporary development paradigm and <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n policy<br />
making in the 1990s, in Transformation in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>? Policy debates in the<br />
1990s, edited by E Maganya & R Houghton. Johannesburg: Institute for <strong>Africa</strong>n<br />
Alternatives.<br />
Maharaj, B & Rambali, K 1998. Local economic development strategies in an emerging<br />
democracy: the case <strong>of</strong> Durban in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Urban Studies 35(1):131±148.<br />
Mannikuti, S 1997. Community participation: so what? Evidence from a comparative<br />
study <strong>of</strong> two rural water supply and sanitation projects in India. Development<br />
Policy Review 15.<br />
Marcus, T, Eales, K & Wildschut, A 1996. Down to earth: land demand in the new <strong>South</strong><br />
<strong>Africa</strong>. Durban: Indicator.<br />
Martin, M 1994. Developing a feminist participative research framework: evaluating the<br />
process, in Re-thinking social research, edited by B Humphries & C Truman.<br />
Aldershot: Avebury.<br />
Martin, A & Sherington, J 1997. Participatory research methods: implementation, effectiveness<br />
and institutional context. Agricultural Systems 55(2).<br />
Mayoux, L 1995. Beyond naivety: women gender inequality and participatory development.<br />
Development and Change 26.<br />
Mearns, R 1996. Community, collective action and common grazing: the case <strong>of</strong> postsocialist<br />
Mongolia. The Journal <strong>of</strong> Development Studies 32(3):297±339.<br />
Mosse, D 1994. Authority, gender and knowledge: theoretical reflections on the practice<br />
<strong>of</strong> participatory rural appraisal. Development and Change 25.<br />
Oakley, P 1995. People's participation in development projects: a critical review <strong>of</strong><br />
current theory and practice. Oxford: International NGO Training and Research<br />
Centre. (Occasional Papers Series, no 7.)<br />
Rahnema, M 1993. Participation, in The development dictionary, edited by W Sachs.<br />
Johannesburg: Witwatersrand <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />
Schoones, I, Chibudu, C, Chikura, S, Jeranyama, P, Machaka, D, Machanja, W, Mavedzenge,<br />
B, Mombeshora, B, Mudhara, M, Mudziwo, C, Murimbarima, F & Zirereza,<br />
B 1996. Hazards and opportunities farming livelihoods in dryland <strong>Africa</strong>:<br />
lessons from Zimbabwe. London: Zed.<br />
Schoones, I 1997. The dynamics <strong>of</strong> soil fertility change: historical perspectives on environmental<br />
transformation from Zimbabwe. The Geographical Journal 163(2).<br />
Selener, D 1997. Participatory Action Research and social change. Cornell: Cornell<br />
Participatory Action Research Network.<br />
Young, I M 1994. Civil society and social change. Theoria, October:73±94.<br />
Uph<strong>of</strong>f, N, Wickramsinghe, M L & Wijayaratna, C M 1990. `Optimum' participation in<br />
irrigation management: issues and evidence from Sri Lanka. Human Organisation<br />
49(1):26±40.<br />
75
Revenue and ownership Ð the<br />
impact <strong>of</strong> privatisation in <strong>South</strong><br />
<strong>Africa</strong>: lessons from the UK<br />
Charles C Okeahalam and<br />
Royson M Mukwena*<br />
ABSTRACT<br />
This paper uses anecdotal evidence from the United Kingdom to suggest<br />
that one <strong>of</strong> the most trusted ways <strong>of</strong> ensuring the long-term development and<br />
growth prospects <strong>of</strong> the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n economy is to develop the philosophy<br />
<strong>of</strong> the stakeholder amongst all <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>ns via a carefully planned and<br />
implemented privatisation programme. The paper concentrates on two aspects<br />
<strong>of</strong> privatisation: the impact on government revenues on the one hand,<br />
and the impact on share ownership by employees and on the welfare <strong>of</strong> RSA<br />
citizen stakeholders on the other hand. Market-led proposals are a desirable<br />
method <strong>of</strong> ensuring long-term benefits for all <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>'s citizens. Potential<br />
consequences <strong>of</strong> market failure are also discussed.<br />
* The authors are grateful to Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Ron Hope <strong>of</strong> the <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Botswana for his helpful<br />
comments.<br />
1 INTRODUCTION<br />
This paper uses the UK privatisation experience to illustrate some <strong>of</strong> the benefits<br />
and problems <strong>of</strong> privatisation and it relates this experience to the debate on<br />
privatisation in the Republic <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> (RSA). It suggests that determining<br />
an appropriate privatisation policy is difficult, varies from country to country, and<br />
should be influenced by the underlying objective behind the particular privatisation<br />
process.<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>nus <strong>30</strong>(2)2000 76
Although privatisation policy impacts on a variety <strong>of</strong> issues, this paper concentrates<br />
on two objectives which are important in the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n context.<br />
The first is privatisation as a source <strong>of</strong> government revenue and the second is<br />
privatisation as a method <strong>of</strong> increasing employee ownership and perceived<br />
control, so as to increase economic efficiency and labour productivity.<br />
2 PRIVATISATION POLICY<br />
The United Kingdom has played a role in developing and implementing the<br />
ideas and practice <strong>of</strong> privatisation. <strong>No</strong>w that apartheid has been overcome, the<br />
next major challenge facing the government <strong>of</strong> the Republic <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong><br />
(RSA) is to improve the economic wellbeing <strong>of</strong> the many previously disenfranchised<br />
citizens. In its 1993 election campaign the <strong>Africa</strong>n National Congress<br />
(ANC) made several welfare pledges to the electorate. <strong>No</strong>w that it has formed<br />
the government, their expectations have been kindled.<br />
Privatisation may be used by the government to raise revenues and improve<br />
fiscal balances to meet its welfare policy objectives. As the World Bank (1995)<br />
has argued, privatisation is justified on the ground that state-owned enterprises<br />
(SOEs) are invariably inefficient and therefore constitute a massive drain on<br />
limited public resources. Vickers and Yarrow (1988) and Vickers and Yarrow<br />
(1991) identify three major types <strong>of</strong> privatisation: firstly, the privatisation <strong>of</strong><br />
competitive companies, that is the transfer to the private sector <strong>of</strong> companies<br />
operating within competitive product markets with low market failure; 1 secondly,<br />
the privatisation <strong>of</strong> monopolies, that is the transfer to the private sector <strong>of</strong> firms<br />
with significant market power; and thirdly, the contracting out <strong>of</strong> public services<br />
to the private sector.<br />
The first step in formulating privatisation policy is to decide on the objectives<br />
and type <strong>of</strong> privatisation programme. When privatisation takes place via state<br />
asset disposal, the government has to decide on the objectives <strong>of</strong> the exercise.<br />
The objective might be to dispose <strong>of</strong> a loss-making enterprise to reduce the<br />
negative impact on tax payers. Another objective might be to place governmentmanaged<br />
concerns within a market environment, in other words without government<br />
subsidy. This would result in increased efficiency, better rates <strong>of</strong> financial<br />
return and improved management. Accordingly, decisions on the nature<br />
<strong>of</strong> privatisation policy in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> need to be seen as part <strong>of</strong> an overall<br />
economic strategy to improve the performance <strong>of</strong> the economy.<br />
Veljanovski (1989), amongst others, highlights the success <strong>of</strong> privatisation in<br />
the developed market economies where active, dynamic capital markets exist.<br />
However, it should be obvious that privatisation policy may not yield the same<br />
77
outcome in a developing economy with a limited capital market. The ``best''<br />
privatisation policy will be determined by the nature <strong>of</strong> the problems which it<br />
seeks to address, and by the environment within which it is being implemented.<br />
For example, a government may believe that privatisation would improve efficiency<br />
and generate higher fiscal revenues. To this effect it may decide to<br />
privatise an inefficient, monopolistic state-owned utility. It might choose to allocate<br />
shares to the private sector via a flotation so as to minimise the probability<br />
<strong>of</strong> market failure and loss <strong>of</strong> the benefits <strong>of</strong> revenues. On the other hand,<br />
it may choose a voucher system which, in theory, would allow members <strong>of</strong> the<br />
public equivalent access to a certain number <strong>of</strong> shares in the utility. Theoretically<br />
this would increase the likelihood <strong>of</strong> maximising the welfare <strong>of</strong> all taxpayers.<br />
However, if the objective <strong>of</strong> the privatisation is to maximise revenue<br />
from the disposal <strong>of</strong> the utility, then it is unlikely that the voucher system will<br />
achieve the objective, because the social cost <strong>of</strong> government intervention, that<br />
is the impact <strong>of</strong> government failure, will reduce the financial returns. On the<br />
other hand, if a flotation is carried out to attempt to maximise government<br />
revenues, this may have a high welfare cost.<br />
2.1 Ownership<br />
Related to this issue <strong>of</strong> the ``best'' privatisation policy is the debate on the<br />
impact <strong>of</strong> ownership on economic performance. The effects <strong>of</strong> changes in<br />
ownership and competitive market conditions on economic performance are<br />
well documented (Pryke 1982; Fubara 1985; Hartley et al 1991; Vickers &<br />
Yarrow 1991; Okonkwo 1991; Parker 1992). The evidence suggests that the<br />
nominal change <strong>of</strong> ownership does not in itself guarantee increased performance.<br />
What appears to be important, is the impact that the movement to the<br />
private sector has on incentive mechanisms within the organisations. Unlike the<br />
case <strong>of</strong> the private sector, in the public sector there are limited worker and<br />
managerial incentives, and this reduces labour motivation and managerial initiative.<br />
Furthermore, in a highly regulated environment a change <strong>of</strong> ownership<br />
limits the actual impact which privatisation may make. The paradox is that<br />
governments need not intervene in truly competitive markets unless there are<br />
obvious signs <strong>of</strong> market failure. Government intervention in the form <strong>of</strong> regulation<br />
is usually only necessary where government has privatised a corporation<br />
which is likely to generate market failure, such as privatised monopolies.<br />
The privatisation <strong>of</strong> a monopoly supplier is evidence <strong>of</strong> government failure. 2 But<br />
it is not best policy to attempt to use regulation to rectify this type <strong>of</strong> problem,<br />
since in such circumstances market failure will continue and the change <strong>of</strong><br />
ownership does not remove it.<br />
78
2.2 Efficiency<br />
There is also debate as to whether privatisation improves efficiency. Parker<br />
(1992) suggests that certain factors, such as improved use <strong>of</strong> resources and<br />
control <strong>of</strong> operational cost, may determine the success <strong>of</strong> privatisation according<br />
to the criterion <strong>of</strong> efficiency. This is particularly so when the incentive to<br />
increase efficiency through the introduction <strong>of</strong> competition is lacking, especially<br />
if the firms under consideration are large monopolistic suppliers <strong>of</strong> services,<br />
such as Telkom and Eskom, 3 or other highly capital-intensive product suppliers<br />
which have high entry costs. 4<br />
Economists have identified two types <strong>of</strong> inefficiency in a public sector enterprise<br />
which may present a case for privatisation. The first is allocative inefficiency, in<br />
other words an inefficient use <strong>of</strong> raw materials. The argument is that public<br />
sector enterprises have allocative inefficiencies because <strong>of</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> competition;<br />
therefore transferring them to the private sector, where they will face competition,<br />
will improve their use <strong>of</strong> resources.<br />
The second major type <strong>of</strong> inefficiency is productive or technical inefficiency.<br />
Productive inefficiency occurs when public enterprises do not minimise costs,<br />
since they are shielded from the adverse consequences <strong>of</strong> such behaviour. De<br />
Borger (1993) and Yosha (1995) have questioned whether productive efficiency<br />
will improve as a result <strong>of</strong> transfer <strong>of</strong> ownership. One point <strong>of</strong> view is that it will<br />
improve irrespective <strong>of</strong> ownership since it is determined mostly by organisational<br />
arrangements. An opposite view is that transferring the enterprise from<br />
the public to private sector should have an effect, since managerial and organisational<br />
arrangements are related to the type <strong>of</strong> ownership.<br />
This debate is very important to privatisation primarily because, as Hutchinson<br />
(1991) suggests, the impetus for privatisation is partly driven by the belief that<br />
public enterprises do not behave in a cost-minimising manner. Accordingly, if<br />
transferring these enterprises to the private sector has no impact on efficiency,<br />
the need for privatisation is reduced. This was the UK Trade Union Congress<br />
(TUC) view in the early 1980s and it has been expressed consistently by the<br />
Congress <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n Trade Unions (COSATU). COSATU suggests that<br />
the inefficiencies <strong>of</strong> public enterprises in the RSA are the result <strong>of</strong> apartheid,<br />
and that the recent political changes will enable more efficient aggregate welfare-enhancing<br />
economic policies, which will result in increased efficiency and<br />
performance in public enterprises. While this argument does have some merit,<br />
the evidence from the rest <strong>of</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> suggests that political freedom<br />
has not manifested itself in economic rights Ð so there is still ongoing debate<br />
as to the impact which privatisation and ownership have on efficiency.<br />
79
3 A BRIEF OVERVIEW OF THE SOUTH AFRICAN ECONOMY<br />
``Best'' privatisation policy is not designed in a vacuum, so it is necessary to<br />
briefly present some elements <strong>of</strong> the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n economy.<br />
One <strong>of</strong> the legacies <strong>of</strong> apartheid in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> is the obfuscation <strong>of</strong> economic<br />
facts for ideological and political reasons. This has made evaluating true economic<br />
performance in the RSA difficult. However, it is still possible to suggest<br />
that the mixture <strong>of</strong> bad political judgement and the impact <strong>of</strong> economic sanctions<br />
meant that in the past the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n economy performed less efficiently<br />
than it might have, given the economic fundamentals <strong>of</strong> the country. In<br />
addition the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> economy is characterised by large disparities which<br />
are readily apparent when economic indicators are disaggregated by race.<br />
Table 1 Summary <strong>of</strong> relevant economic indicators in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong><br />
Black (1997) White (1997)<br />
Population (1) 36.2 m 8.3 m<br />
GDP per capita: (US dollars) 641 6 350<br />
Savings ratio (2) 1.4% 7.3%<br />
Unemployment (3) 29.1% 6.4%<br />
Percentage owners <strong>of</strong> private houses 6.7% 39.1%<br />
(fixed mortgage investment) (4)<br />
Level <strong>of</strong> formal education (4) attained:<br />
Nil 39,7% 1,3%<br />
Primary 42.4% 38.8%<br />
Secondary 17.8% 52.1%<br />
Tertiary/university 0.8% 7.9%<br />
Worker population<br />
Blue collar % (5) 87.3% 27.4%<br />
White collar % (6) 12.1% 61.3%<br />
<strong>No</strong>tes to table 1<br />
(1) Total population (1997) figures = 44.5 million. This includes the former ``independent''<br />
homelands, which in 1994 had an approximate population <strong>of</strong> 9.7 million.<br />
(2) Savings ratio defined as ratio <strong>of</strong> personal savings to personal disposable income. Different<br />
marginal income taxes affect accuracy <strong>of</strong> this calculation.<br />
80
(3) Source: Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) (1998), <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce and<br />
Congress <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> Trade Unions (COSATU). One <strong>of</strong> the many nefarious activities <strong>of</strong><br />
apartheid has been to underplay the scale <strong>of</strong> black unemployment while highlighting<br />
employment difficulties or levels <strong>of</strong> unemployment among other racial groups.<br />
(4) Sources: World Trade Tables (1997) Ð Johns Hopkins <strong>University</strong> Press and EIU (1997).<br />
(5) Source: World Trade Tables (1997) Ð Johns Hopkins <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />
(6) Source: Social Indicators <strong>of</strong> Development (1995±1997) Ð World Bank and Johns Hopkins<br />
<strong>University</strong> Press. Includes manual/home help/domestics. This difference reflects the market<br />
mechanism for the manual/non-manual labour relationship. Most whites do indirect manual<br />
work: if their work has a manual classification, then it is usually in a supervisory capacity or other<br />
indirect form.<br />
Table 1 above presents a summary <strong>of</strong> some economic indicators which reflect<br />
the racial inequalities in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Economic statistics on the RSA, in particular<br />
figures on the level <strong>of</strong> unemployment disaggregated by race, have been<br />
the subject <strong>of</strong> much debate and dispute. The figures in table 1 were taken from<br />
the Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) and from the World Trade Tables published<br />
by Johns Hopkins Press. Given the credibility <strong>of</strong> the sources <strong>of</strong> the<br />
figures used in this table, they are assumed to be reliable.<br />
Income distribution and racial economic inequality has to be considered when<br />
free market economic policy, such as privatisation, is proposed. For example,<br />
the Economist magazine recently reported that in 1993 <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> had a per<br />
capita GDP figure <strong>of</strong> US$3 010. This would place it on comparable terms with<br />
the wealthier Latin American countries and countries in Eastern Europe such as<br />
Hungary. However, this is an aggregated figure. When disaggregated along<br />
racial lines, white GDP per capita rises to US$6 350, similar to the levels <strong>of</strong><br />
Spain and Greece, whilst per capita income for blacks drops to US$641, closer<br />
to the levels <strong>of</strong> Zimbabwe (US$590) and much lower than Botswana<br />
(US$1 400). So by using just the GDP per capita measure it is easy to identify<br />
the obvious demarcation with which the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n economy can be assessed.<br />
Morally, and indeed from a sound economic welfare perspective, there<br />
is reason to believe that this extreme difference is not only unjust, but economically<br />
inefficient.<br />
Accordingly, moral arguments and economic imperatives call for some form <strong>of</strong><br />
economic redistribution in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Indeed, Perotti (1993) provides evidence<br />
that effective redistribution in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> may also lead to economic<br />
growth. Perotti also shows that, in theory, with linear income taxes and revenues,<br />
there is a strong possibility for the ``trickle-down'' phenomenon to take<br />
place. Furthermore, one <strong>of</strong> the likely positive spillover effects would be an<br />
81
increase in investment in education by the lower income group, which would<br />
boost their future incomes. It could also be argued that, given their share <strong>of</strong><br />
investment capital (see table 1), the higher income group would benefit indirectly<br />
as a result <strong>of</strong> having a better educated and more internationally competitive<br />
workforce. Yet for this to take place, the highest income group has to<br />
ensure that the size <strong>of</strong> whatever ``trickles down'' is large enough to ensure that<br />
the opportunity cost <strong>of</strong> low income earners seeking further education is not so<br />
high as to dissuade them from doing so; in other words, marginal benefits from<br />
education for the low income group have to increase. Privatisation presents an<br />
opportunity to achieve this objective without policies <strong>of</strong> overt government intervention,<br />
which have been discredited elsewhere.<br />
4 PRIVATISATION AS A SOURCE OF GOVERNMENT REVENUE<br />
4.1 Methods <strong>of</strong> evaluating the revenue effects <strong>of</strong> privatisation<br />
A well-managed privatisation programme can be an effective method <strong>of</strong> revenue<br />
generation. Efficient revenue generation is an important aspect <strong>of</strong> the<br />
<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n government's macroeconomic growth, employment, and redistribution<br />
strategy (GEAR). Since monopolies are worth more than competitive<br />
firms, a government concerned with maximising the revenue derived from the<br />
sale <strong>of</strong> public assets is unlikely to implement competitive liberalising policy. 5<br />
Some <strong>of</strong> the evidence from the UK is fairly instructive in this regard. For example,<br />
this reasoning led to the disposal <strong>of</strong> British Telecom and British Gas as<br />
monopolies. It may be safely suggested that the proceeds from the privatisation<br />
<strong>of</strong> UK government equity holdings through the privatisation process had enabled<br />
the Conservative government <strong>of</strong> 1983±1987 not only to reduce the public<br />
sector borrowing requirement (PSBR), but to place it in a position <strong>of</strong> debt repayment.<br />
For example, Kay and Thompson (1986) show that the sale <strong>of</strong> British<br />
Telecom reduced the public sector borrowing requirement by $770 million<br />
during the 1985/86 fiscal year.<br />
A government interested in short-term revenue maximisation from the sale <strong>of</strong><br />
public assets is unlikely to support extensive liberalisation policy. So one<br />
method <strong>of</strong> evaluating the revenue effects <strong>of</strong> privatisation is to examine public<br />
sector performance and the impact it has on the public sector borrowing requirement.<br />
According to this method, asset sales may be treated as revenue<br />
receipts and cash transactions are recorded without reference to the impact<br />
they may have on future inflows and outflows <strong>of</strong> capital, or to the way these<br />
82
transactions alter other short- or long-term properties <strong>of</strong> the government balance<br />
sheet. This method cannot be recommended. It is incorrect to treat these<br />
receipts as one would treat other items <strong>of</strong> government revenue, because any<br />
advantage <strong>of</strong> treating the receipts in this way is likely to be short-term. The only<br />
additional benefit is that equity-type asset portfolios derived from shares in state<br />
industries might be more acceptable to the capital market than traditional<br />
methods <strong>of</strong> government borrowing, such as issuing bonds.<br />
Irrespective <strong>of</strong> the problems associated with the use <strong>of</strong> public sector cash accounting<br />
or private sector accrual accounting, or whether or not the firm is a<br />
monopoly or competitive market operator, the determination <strong>of</strong> financial gain or<br />
loss from the asset disposal depends on whether or not the price paid is greater<br />
than, or less than the present value <strong>of</strong> prospective earnings from the asset.<br />
Since privatisation policy is <strong>of</strong>ten used by a government concerned with<br />
keeping its public sector borrowing requirement (PSBR) under control, it is<br />
sometimes necessary to convince investors <strong>of</strong> the credibility <strong>of</strong> its low inflation<br />
policy and the positive impact on future corporate earnings, otherwise the<br />
government may still face short-term financing constraints.<br />
Effective economic management requires appropriate control <strong>of</strong> public sector<br />
borrowing (relative to the GDP), to ensure that income streams (fiscal revenues<br />
and dividends) are able to meet current account demands. A failure to do so<br />
might cause investors holding government securities to reassess the risk premium<br />
<strong>of</strong> holding government debt as collateral. Investors would then either<br />
demand higher real rates <strong>of</strong> return or, in extreme cases, reduce the demand for<br />
government debt issue, prompting a likely increase in real interest rates.<br />
Accordingly, the disposal <strong>of</strong> parts <strong>of</strong> public sector holdings in a privatisation<br />
policy is similar to the selling <strong>of</strong> equity. However, in a less developed economy<br />
this fact is <strong>of</strong> little help in deciding on what discount rate to use to price public<br />
sector assets prior to privatisation (Okeahalam 1997). This is a problem even in<br />
developed market economies, where capital markets are relatively liquid, and<br />
bonds (corporate and government) can be priced easily (Menyah et al 1990).<br />
Therefore, using the bond markets to generate borrowing may appear to be less<br />
costly than issuing equity. However, in economies where the bond markets are<br />
less liquid, particularly in highly indebted countries where the probability <strong>of</strong><br />
inflation eroding the real value <strong>of</strong> returns is high, issuing equity, that is privatisation<br />
(despite its higher transaction cost) may actually be a cheaper way to<br />
generate revenue than issuing bonds.<br />
83
4.2 Private investor returns and public sector regulation<br />
For this to take place in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, private sector investors will have to be<br />
convinced that there will not be a reduction in the commitment <strong>of</strong> government to<br />
adhere to the pr<strong>of</strong>essed economic policy. This will be conditioned by a number<br />
<strong>of</strong> factors. Firstly, equity investors have to take into account the risk <strong>of</strong> renationalisation,<br />
in the event <strong>of</strong> a change in government or policy. This applies, in<br />
particular, to foreign investors. Secondly, the probability <strong>of</strong> government default<br />
would vary from industry to industry.<br />
There is also a need to be aware <strong>of</strong> changing the regulatory framework. An<br />
extremely pr<strong>of</strong>itable or potentially pr<strong>of</strong>itable public sector (most probably<br />
monopolistic) operation is likely to be evaluated at a premium by investors.<br />
However, monopolistic pr<strong>of</strong>itability is perceived differently when it takes place in<br />
the public sector and pr<strong>of</strong>its accrue to the government exchequer than when the<br />
pr<strong>of</strong>its accrue to private investors. Both pr<strong>of</strong>its are achieved at cost to the<br />
consumer. On the other hand, a public sector monopolistic supplier may not<br />
make as much net pr<strong>of</strong>it as it might have realised had it been transferred to the<br />
private sector, yet the true cost to consumers may actually decrease consumer<br />
welfare by a greater extent. In other words, the lower level <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> the public<br />
sector firm may not be price related, but may be a function <strong>of</strong> a lower level <strong>of</strong><br />
efficiency. Therefore, even if the quality <strong>of</strong> service level at the financial price<br />
charged is nominally lower, it may actually have a higher economic price.<br />
Pr<strong>of</strong>it should be a component <strong>of</strong> the welfare function <strong>of</strong> both the public and<br />
private sectors Ð indeed the welfare function is not fully maximised without<br />
pr<strong>of</strong>its. However, this does not remove the probability that consumers will rally<br />
against the level <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> publicly owned monopolistic companies which<br />
have been transferred to the private sector. The evidence (Marsh 1991; Veljanovski<br />
1989) suggests that the best way to overcome this problem is not<br />
through high regulation, but by the introduction <strong>of</strong> competition. Of course this<br />
will be easier to achieve where cost <strong>of</strong> entry is low. By definition this is more<br />
difficult in capital-intensive industries with high sunk costs such as electricity<br />
(Eskom), transport (Transnet), and telecommunications (Telkom). One way <strong>of</strong><br />
addressing this problem is through franchising. The government has then to<br />
compare the cost <strong>of</strong> providing true competition (via fiscal measures, differential<br />
rates <strong>of</strong> tax for startup companies, etc) with the social welfare costs to the<br />
consumer.<br />
Although high levels <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>itability or prices do not by themselves provide direct<br />
84
evidence for monopolistic (or lack <strong>of</strong> competitive) behaviour, they are <strong>of</strong>ten<br />
referred to in discussions on consumer welfare. A good example <strong>of</strong> this may be<br />
found in the experience <strong>of</strong> the water utilities in the UK. Water supply on the<br />
British mainland used to be controlled by ten regional water authorities which<br />
enjoyed a monopoly because <strong>of</strong> the nature <strong>of</strong> water supply. There has been<br />
consumer pressure to improve water quality to meet the European Community<br />
(EC) standard. This would require higher capital investment. To overcome the<br />
problem that privatised water utilities would under-invest, the British government<br />
implicitly agreed that price controls would be such that it would allow for<br />
positive returns on investment in new water infrastructure. In effect, the government<br />
made ``regulatory contracts'' (Vickers & Yarrow 1991) with the utilities<br />
to enable them to obtain infrastructure finance from consumers. Yet after privatisation<br />
the water companies had to make higher, but different levels <strong>of</strong> investment<br />
to achieve the EC standard. Those that had to raise the most finance<br />
to meet the EC standard were not necessarily those that had the largest revenue,<br />
the largest number <strong>of</strong> consumers, or the highest mean unit financial<br />
return per consumer. Furthermore, the intra-industry cost <strong>of</strong> obtaining commercial<br />
finance measured by project finance interest rates varied by as much as<br />
1.2 percent. So, the regulatory contract had created price differentials and<br />
further confounded the consumer-welfare price argument, as it became easier<br />
for the water companies to explain price rises via the cost <strong>of</strong> improving water<br />
quality. However, the marginal improvement in quality did not compensate for<br />
the marginal increase in price, since the price increases for quality were not<br />
uniform.<br />
Accordingly, De Fraja (1991) has shown that the full privatisation <strong>of</strong> a large,<br />
inefficient monopoly in the public sector into an oligopolistic market may have<br />
an adverse welfare effect. The argument is that entry by an inefficient but<br />
welfare-maximising public enterprise into an oligopolistic, pr<strong>of</strong>it-maximising industry<br />
in the private sector may reduce the pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>of</strong> the market incumbents. 6 As<br />
Kay and Thompson (1986) point out,<br />
If as we have argued the privatisation <strong>of</strong> large dominant firms is at best<br />
pointless and possibly harmful in the absence <strong>of</strong> effective competition, the<br />
result is that no benefits to economic performance are likely to be achieved.<br />
Privatisation <strong>of</strong> this type would not be the first ineffectual restructuring <strong>of</strong><br />
relationships between government and the nationalised industries ... it is<br />
potentially more damaging than the others because privatisation makes it<br />
more difficult to introduce competitive incentives in the future.<br />
85
Yet for government revenue reasons this is the type <strong>of</strong> privatisation that usually<br />
takes place. The actual observed social results achieved do not match the hype<br />
which privatisation has been accorded in political economy (Parker 1992).<br />
5 PRIVATISATION AS A METHOD OF INCREASING EMPLOYEE<br />
SHARE OWNERSHIP<br />
5.1 Introduction<br />
The second major area <strong>of</strong> privatisation which this paper addresses relates to<br />
employee share ownership. This type <strong>of</strong> privatisation may take several forms,<br />
for instance, (i) a trade union-led employee buyout involving all employees; (ii)<br />
an employee share ownership plan (through a trust) involving all employees;<br />
and (iii) an <strong>of</strong>fered management-led employee buyout involving all employees<br />
(Wright & Buck 1992: 284). Employee ownership in its various forms has the<br />
potential to transform an economy, because it is concerned with the distribution<br />
<strong>of</strong> future wealth rather than the distribution <strong>of</strong> present wealth. Furthermore, it<br />
provides incentives both to capital and to labour, through its effect on efficiency,<br />
productivity and motivation. A proposal that seeks to redress the glaring imbalances<br />
in wealth distribution in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> should consider this form <strong>of</strong><br />
privatisation, particularly in the light <strong>of</strong> the political history <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. It<br />
could reduce the probability <strong>of</strong> political discord, especially when (for reasons <strong>of</strong><br />
government asset sales revenue-maximisation) potential local investors feel<br />
excluded from the privatisation. As Wright and Buck (1992: 286) observe, one<br />
attraction <strong>of</strong> buyouts is that they <strong>of</strong>fer a significant amount <strong>of</strong> indigenous<br />
ownership, whereas foreign ownership may pose political problems. It might<br />
also increase industrial efficiency and sectoral competitiveness by increasing<br />
worker commitment; 7 reduce the probability <strong>of</strong> strike action, since the workforce<br />
may on aggregate have a reduced ``them and us'' philosophy; increase the<br />
volume <strong>of</strong> domestically-derived transactions in the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n equity and<br />
capital markets; and, therefore, lead to a reduction in the perceived opportunity<br />
cost <strong>of</strong> foreign investment in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. It is noteworthy that when the GNU<br />
was in power, discussions along these lines took place between the GNU, the<br />
Congress <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n Trade Unions (COSATU), representatives <strong>of</strong> business<br />
and the private sector, and other stakeholders.<br />
In the UK, employee buyouts achieved great success when the privatisation<br />
process there was still at an early stage <strong>of</strong> development. An <strong>of</strong>ten-cited example<br />
<strong>of</strong> this period <strong>of</strong> employee buyout privatisation success in the UK is<br />
86
National Freight Consortium, which was sold to its employees in 1983. Yet the<br />
extensive use <strong>of</strong> employee buyouts at that time was partially to ensure that any<br />
pr<strong>of</strong>its which accrued from privatised public enterprises would be spread as<br />
widely as the income distribution would allow. It was also thought that this type<br />
<strong>of</strong> privatisation policy in particular might possibly alter the income distribution<br />
pattern Ð this is the Thatcherite ``economic classless society'' argument Ð<br />
and, therefore, increase the probability <strong>of</strong> participating and receiving the financial<br />
benefits <strong>of</strong> the privatisation. 8<br />
5.2 The impact <strong>of</strong> income differentials and savings on employment<br />
buyouts<br />
The major drawback to the effective implementation <strong>of</strong> this policy in <strong>South</strong><br />
<strong>Africa</strong> (as it was to a lesser extent in the UK), is the large disparity in personal<br />
income (revenue) and level <strong>of</strong> capital (savings) among blacks and whites in<br />
<strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> (see table 1). This would have implications for the ability <strong>of</strong> some<br />
(in particular non-white employees and managers) to take advantage <strong>of</strong> the<br />
range <strong>of</strong> financing and institutional structures required to implement an effective<br />
employee or management buyout. Typically employees and managers in British<br />
buyout teams have had to place substantial personal capital at risk when participating<br />
in buyout teams. This is because in the UK, the method used has<br />
been for the buyout team Ð usually the management <strong>of</strong> the firm Ð to establish<br />
a nominally new company which would buy out the business. Members <strong>of</strong> the<br />
buyout team become the new company's directors (employees, ie non-managerial<br />
staff, are usually represented by the most senior manager in their department).<br />
This gives the buyout team a limited liability status. Accordingly, it is<br />
the new company which must now raise the necessary finance to acquire the<br />
business. However, some employees in the UK have been unable to participate<br />
in the buyout, particularly when they had no assets as collateral. 9 It is likely that<br />
a larger number <strong>of</strong> employees would have participated in buyouts in the UK,<br />
had they had the collateral with which to raise the finance to participate.<br />
One way <strong>of</strong> solving this problem <strong>of</strong> a lack <strong>of</strong> collateral is to re-mortgage one's<br />
home. Apart from its immediate utility, home ownership serves indirectly as a<br />
typical source <strong>of</strong> leverage collateral. However, the level <strong>of</strong> home ownership<br />
among non-whites in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> is relatively low. Furthermore, the present<br />
uneven distribution <strong>of</strong> land in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> might also affect the implementation<br />
<strong>of</strong> employee buyouts and other attempts by blacks to become economic<br />
stakeholders. The Land and Agricultural Bank needs to play a role in estab-<br />
87
lishing a mechanism for a reasonable market-value based white-to-black private<br />
land redistribution in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. This is important, since any bank or<br />
group participating in the financing <strong>of</strong> black employee buyouts would have to<br />
make broader assessments <strong>of</strong> the definition <strong>of</strong> collateral in deciding whether to<br />
finance these interests.<br />
5.3 Government failure in employee buyouts<br />
It seems as though the government should play a greater role in helping to<br />
facilitate employee buyouts, since financiers (banks, building societies and<br />
other private-sector financial institutions) are unlikely to participate, unless their<br />
risks are underwritten by another party. However, that may create government<br />
failure, since there is a possibility that a bureaucratic or political agenda may<br />
interfere with optimal allocation in the underwriting process: the bureaucratic<br />
objective may begin to override the optimal market-derived social welfare<br />
function, resulting in government failure. Furthermore, government underwriting<br />
<strong>of</strong> the financing in an employee buyout may have an effect on the distinction <strong>of</strong><br />
ownership <strong>of</strong> the company. This matter is important, because as discussed,<br />
earlier research (Vickers & Yarrow 1988; Parker & Hartley 1991; Hartley et al<br />
1991) has shown that nominal change in ownership is unimportant, and that<br />
there is little difference between a private company in a highly regulated industry<br />
and a public enterprise. What appears to be most important, is the<br />
perceived allocation <strong>of</strong> risks and returns.<br />
Overt government intervention (government failure), directly or indirectly, in the<br />
financing <strong>of</strong> employee buyouts may confound the question <strong>of</strong> ownership. In<br />
such cases, the change or nominal change <strong>of</strong> ownership is unimportant.<br />
However, Pirie (1992) suggests that ownership is important and that the very<br />
act <strong>of</strong> transfer to the private sector yields market benefits. But Pirie does not<br />
fully explain what the social costs <strong>of</strong> market failure may be if, or when, private<br />
sector ownership is not socially optimal. Bearing in mind the political circumstances<br />
in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, it is also naive to argue, as free market theorists such<br />
as Pirie have done, that these social costs are irrelevant since the market<br />
equilibrium in the distribution <strong>of</strong> ownership rights is the long-term optimal solution.<br />
5.4 Market failure in employee buyouts<br />
With regard to employee buyouts, two forms <strong>of</strong> market failure may take place.<br />
88
Firstly, the price at which shares in the new company are issued may be so high<br />
that very few employees can actually participate in the issue, or if they do so,<br />
and the issue is a success, they then trade their shares at a pr<strong>of</strong>it. This might<br />
defeat the distribution welfare objective for short-term returns. Secondly, the<br />
market price may be so high that the institutions play a bigger role in the<br />
financing <strong>of</strong> the buyout than the employees. Even if the employees are the<br />
majority share holders, there is still the difficulty that a significant group <strong>of</strong> share<br />
holders do not take the same view with regard to the management <strong>of</strong> the<br />
company. This type <strong>of</strong> division may decrease the expected benefits <strong>of</strong> buyouts,<br />
such as motivation, increased efficiency, productivity and pr<strong>of</strong>its.<br />
There may therefore be a temptation for the mispricing <strong>of</strong> government assets to<br />
ensure the success <strong>of</strong> a privatisation programme. From a strictly financial<br />
perspective there is empirical evidence (Menyah et al 1990) <strong>of</strong> mispricing in the<br />
UK. Indeed Brittan (1986) has suggested that this was carried out to achieve<br />
not only financial objectives <strong>of</strong> the transfer <strong>of</strong> ownership, but also political objectives.<br />
It is not clear what pricing framework will be used in <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n<br />
privatisation, and therefore it is at the moment difficult to see whether state<br />
assets are being mispriced for political reasons.<br />
In any event, apart from the issue <strong>of</strong> who pays for the difference between the<br />
market price and the socially optimal privatisation price, there should be little or<br />
no reason why the government should not discount the asset cost to local<br />
employees <strong>of</strong> participating in employee buyouts. This would increase the likelihood<br />
<strong>of</strong> creating a local investor base which might then actively participate in<br />
the other privatisation mechanisms and processes. It is also worth noting that in<br />
the UK, government discount <strong>of</strong> share prices in direct flotations <strong>of</strong> shares during<br />
privatisation <strong>of</strong> enterprises such as British Gas and British Telecom did not<br />
prevent institutional participation. However, the major political problem for the<br />
government is that the vast current racial differences in individual earnings and<br />
savings levels could make this process very expensive. This prompts the<br />
question: what will be the financial cost to the government <strong>of</strong> reserving or<br />
discounting share prices to allow for wider public take-up?<br />
There is also the question <strong>of</strong> the role which domestic, as opposed to foreign<br />
financial institutions, should play as intermediaries. One suggestion is that<br />
domestic institutions would market more effectively locally, and so should be<br />
encouraged to participate; to achieve the more social objective <strong>of</strong> wider domestic<br />
ownership, while foreign financial intermediaries with positive economies<br />
<strong>of</strong> scale and scope should be invited and given incentives to place shares<br />
89
internationally and increase the probability <strong>of</strong> ensuring higher financial returns.<br />
10 Some form <strong>of</strong> differential pricing would be necessary to achieve this.<br />
Table 2 below illustrates a method via which this might be achieved bearing in<br />
mind the above discussion.<br />
Table 2 Possible structure <strong>of</strong> wider share ownership scheme<br />
Class <strong>of</strong> Number <strong>of</strong> shares Government % <strong>of</strong> % revenue<br />
shares multiplied by receipts from each from each<br />
(A, B, C, share price in sales (rand class <strong>of</strong> class (5)<br />
and D) rands millions) share<br />
A 1 750 000 6 19 3 325 m 35% 29%<br />
(1)<br />
B 1 350 000 6 22 3 <strong>30</strong>0 m <strong>30</strong>% <strong>30</strong>%<br />
(2)<br />
C 1 250 000 6 36 4 500 m 25% 40%<br />
(3)<br />
D 500 000 6 2.5 1 125 m 10%<br />
(4)<br />
Total receipts 11 125 m 100%<br />
(A, B, C)<br />
Total capital<br />
12 375 m<br />
<strong>No</strong>tes to table 2<br />
(1) <strong>No</strong>t tradeable within 3 months <strong>of</strong> issue. Perks might include capital gains tax exemption in first<br />
year.<br />
(2) Set period in which shares are not tradeable to foreign investors. Other conditions as for class A<br />
shares.<br />
(3) Foreign investors provide 40 percent <strong>of</strong> the capital but own and have shareholder voting and<br />
other rights <strong>of</strong> 25 percent.<br />
(4) The government share price is the mean <strong>of</strong> the three price entries for class A, B, C. Government<br />
retains 500 000 (10%) with a value <strong>of</strong> 1 250 million.<br />
(5) May not add up due to rounding by spreadsheet.<br />
Finally, to overcome some <strong>of</strong> the problems noted above it might be sensible for<br />
the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n government to distribute shares either freely or in the form <strong>of</strong><br />
some voucher scheme which allows for the uptake <strong>of</strong> shares in the previously<br />
90
nationalised corporations. This system is not novel and has been practised very<br />
successfully in the Czech Republic (Svejnar & Singer 1994) and in various parts<br />
<strong>of</strong> the developing world and emerging markets (Brazil, Hungary, Poland, <strong>South</strong><br />
Korea and Turkey). In such emerging, less-efficient capital markets it is not<br />
unusual to find a discrepancy between the implied market share price <strong>of</strong> the<br />
public sector corporation and the nominal asset-value derived price. The immediate<br />
costs to government is a loss <strong>of</strong> expected sales revenue.<br />
However, whilst this system implies social public funding costs and places<br />
stress on the exchequer, it is more socially fair and may overcome the problem<br />
<strong>of</strong> the expatriation <strong>of</strong> any windfall gains, since the vast majority <strong>of</strong> share holders<br />
would be indigenous. Thus, to reduce the possibility <strong>of</strong> future government intervention<br />
such as nationalisation, it is advisable to introduce some form <strong>of</strong> a<br />
system <strong>of</strong> free distribution <strong>of</strong> shares. In the RSA this may improve the possibility<br />
<strong>of</strong> acceptance <strong>of</strong> privatisation, particularly because income and savings differentials<br />
are high and average personal savings for the majority are low. In the<br />
UK voucher privatisation was initially resisted by the Trade Union Congress<br />
(TUC); however, the exact current position <strong>of</strong> COSATU on this issue is unknown.<br />
6 CONCLUSIONS<br />
We suggest that designing and implementing the privatisation programme will<br />
present the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n Ministry <strong>of</strong> Public Enterprises with significant challenges.<br />
Given the economic history and racial inequality in the RSA, the complexity<br />
<strong>of</strong> effective privatisation would present major challenges to any new<br />
administration. It has already been argued that the prospect <strong>of</strong> the white<br />
business community benefiting from privatisation has been one <strong>of</strong> the main<br />
hurdles preventing RSA from embarking seriously on a privatisation drive<br />
(Bennel 1997: 1786). These challenges may be overcome if proper consideration<br />
is given to the issue <strong>of</strong> individual economic welfare.<br />
This paper has discussed some <strong>of</strong> the issues that should be considered in<br />
evaluating and deciding on privatisation policy for <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. There is still<br />
much debate as to whether or not allocative or productive efficiency is improved<br />
when public enterprises are transferred to the public sector. Similar arguments<br />
apply to the issue <strong>of</strong> ownership, where it would appear that intra-organisational<br />
incentives are more important than actual ownership. The paper also suggests<br />
that introduction <strong>of</strong> competition is an effective and enlightened method <strong>of</strong> reg-<br />
91
ulation. The drawback is that firms in competitive markets are usually less<br />
valuable than monopolistic supplier firms, and therefore governments might<br />
lose revenue if competition is introduced before privatisation. Consequently a<br />
trade-<strong>of</strong>f is <strong>of</strong>ten made between the cost to be borne by the consumer for<br />
monopolistic practices, in comparison to the increased revenues to be derived<br />
by the government. Pure market mechanisms for privatisation usually raise<br />
more money for the government, but they tend to prevent the full participation <strong>of</strong><br />
citizen stakeholders. Therefore, the other major trade <strong>of</strong>f for the government is<br />
usually to decide whether to make the privatisation process as inclusive (vouchers)<br />
as possible, and accept the higher probability <strong>of</strong> lower revenues, or to<br />
use market mechanisms such as flotations and initial public <strong>of</strong>ferings to raise<br />
higher revenues and risk increased alienation <strong>of</strong> low-income citizen stakeholders.<br />
The latter course <strong>of</strong> action may have large political and consumer<br />
welfare implications. Accordingly the debate on efficiency, ownership, competition,<br />
regulation and distribution was used to concentrate on two important<br />
aspects <strong>of</strong> privatisation policy: the impact on government revenue and the<br />
importance <strong>of</strong> wider share ownership via employee buyouts. We used examples<br />
from the UK, where privatisation has been extensive, to further illustrate<br />
these points.<br />
This paper also implies that it is difficult to reverse a well-analysed and implemented<br />
privatisation policy, because the large number <strong>of</strong> citizens that become<br />
shareholders acquire financial interest in the continuation <strong>of</strong> such<br />
economic policy, and therefore in a democracy are less likely to support political<br />
parties or interests which are likely to change such policies. Anecdotal evidence<br />
from the UK suggests that a well-planned and effectively implemented privatisation<br />
policy, which takes into account the economic inequalities and political<br />
history and reality <strong>of</strong> the RSA, can serve as a prudent economic management<br />
tool for wealth creation, and long-term economic growth.<br />
ENDNOTES<br />
1 Strictly speaking, market failure occurs when the forces <strong>of</strong> supply and demand do not yield the<br />
optimal economic outcome or where the optimal economic outcome is itself not the most desired<br />
outcome. Thus the phrase ``market failure'' is also used in the context that unfettered economic<br />
forces do not necessarily bring about desired results, hence even where these forces are<br />
allowed to prevail with limited regulation misallocation <strong>of</strong> resources may still take place.<br />
2 Government failure arises where government intervenes in areas which it can be argued are<br />
best left to market forces. Due to bureaucracy, public sector crowding out, or reduced pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />
incentives, the welfare objectives are not attained, neither are market returns.<br />
3 The British government would argue that British Telecom (BT) and BT itself are operating in a<br />
92
competitive market due to the presence <strong>of</strong> Cable and Wireless Mercury. However, although<br />
efforts have been made by the authorities via the regulatory Office for Telecommunications<br />
(OFTEL), true domestic competition to BT is limited, even though Mercury has made inroads in<br />
international services. British Gas continues to be a monopolistic supplier <strong>of</strong> gas energy.<br />
Competition purists would argue that it is in indirect competition with other forms <strong>of</strong> energy.<br />
4 However, this overlooks the fact that there are energy applications for which the unit cost, and<br />
therefore potential marginal price <strong>of</strong> gas, is less than other alternatives. Consequently the<br />
dominance <strong>of</strong> market supply by one producer distorts optimal consumer choice and welfare.<br />
5 This is why (despite the announcement by the <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n Minister for Telecommunications<br />
that there is to be a telecommunications regulatory authority) Telkom continues to be a<br />
monopolistic land-based telephone operator, in spite <strong>of</strong> the presence <strong>of</strong> cellular entrants. This is<br />
likely to remain the case until privatisation.<br />
6 It is assumed that firms in such an industry do not have pr<strong>of</strong>it levels which deviate substantially<br />
from the mean. The pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> the private sector are such that a slack exists. This slack can be<br />
proxied as a vector <strong>of</strong> variable costs which may be (but are more likely not to be) directly related<br />
to output, and may entail some form <strong>of</strong> managerial incentive to the workforce. However, on entry<br />
and with its pricing policy, the privatised public enterprise firm reduces this slack. So first the<br />
slack erodes, followed by the pr<strong>of</strong>its. Exit <strong>of</strong> firms begins to take place as pr<strong>of</strong>its decline. The<br />
true level <strong>of</strong> consumer choice is reduced as firms exit. The firms that exit may have been fairly<br />
efficient, but in the new competitive framework were unable to make adequate risk-free rate <strong>of</strong><br />
return pr<strong>of</strong>its. In the short term, industry efficiency would increase as incumbent firms try to<br />
compete with the new entrant. However, in the long term industry structure output and market<br />
supply may then well be left to firms which can best mimic the revenue-maximising marginal<br />
price strategy <strong>of</strong> the new entrant. They may not be the most efficient firms. Since industry output<br />
is dominated by inefficient firms, the overall efficiency <strong>of</strong> the industry has declined. For this<br />
argument to hold more fully, the privatised public enterprise must be capable <strong>of</strong> supplying<br />
greater output than its private sector competitors. It could be suggested that ``long run industry<br />
efficiency increases with privatisation if and only if the long run pre-privatisation output <strong>of</strong> the<br />
public firm is lower than that <strong>of</strong> the private oligopolist'' De Fraja (1991). The marginal price may<br />
not cover fixed costs, and in effect the newly privatised firm will be running a budget deficit. It<br />
may very well be possible to finance this deficit through general taxation, but some individuals<br />
would suffer negative welfare effects.<br />
7 A 1986 study (see references) carried out in the US by the National Centre for Employee<br />
Ownership set out to establish whether employee ownership improves commercial performance.<br />
A representative sample <strong>of</strong> employee owned firms was adjusted for size, trade sector<br />
and location and compared with non-employee owned firms. The results <strong>of</strong> the study suggest<br />
that over a five-year period employee owned firms outperformed non-employee owned firms by<br />
40 percent with regard to sales growth and by 46 percent in employment growth. The study also<br />
showed that on the same criteria employee owned firms which had employee participation in<br />
decision making performed better than employee owned firms with limited or, in extreme cases,<br />
no participation.<br />
8 Data from the United Kingdom's Treasury <strong>of</strong>fice and the London Stock Exchange (LSE) indicate<br />
that the number <strong>of</strong> individual shareholders increased from 3 million in 1979 to 9 million in 1988.<br />
Thompson (1993) suggests that the primary reason for this rate <strong>of</strong> growth has been employee<br />
ownership incentive schemes.<br />
9 It would usually be possible for employees to participate at a later date. However, if the buyout<br />
was successful, the price <strong>of</strong> shares in the business would have increased, so the amount <strong>of</strong><br />
capital required by an employee to participate in any subsequent equivalent tranche <strong>of</strong> shares<br />
93
would also increase. In <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> the unions are increasingly using their pension fund assets<br />
to participate in buyouts.<br />
10 This might explain why the Mossgass corporate restructuring deal was awarded to the<br />
consortium <strong>of</strong> Rand Merchant Bank and Deutche Morgan Grenfell in 1996. The Telkom deal<br />
was won by a Malaysian-led consortium, and Hong Kong and Shanghai Bank having acquired<br />
Simpson Mckie, James Capel was appointed as privatisation advisor to the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Public<br />
Enterprises.<br />
BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />
Bennel, P 1997. Privatization in Sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>: progress and prospects during the<br />
1990s. World Development 25(11): 1785±1803.<br />
Brittan, S 1986. Privatisation: a comment on Kay and Thompson. Economic Journal 96,<br />
March: 33±38.<br />
Buckland, R 1990. The costs and returns <strong>of</strong> the privatisation <strong>of</strong> nationalised industries.<br />
Public Administration 68: 241±257.<br />
De Borger, B 1993. The economic environment and public enterprise behaviour: Belgian<br />
Railroads 1950±86. Economica 60: 443±463.<br />
De Fraja, G 1991. Efficiency and privatisation in imperfectly competitive industries.<br />
Journal <strong>of</strong> Industrial Economics 39(3), March: 311±321.<br />
Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) 1998. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>: country pr<strong>of</strong>ile 1997±1998. Annual<br />
survey <strong>of</strong> political and economic background. London: EIU Publishers.<br />
Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) 1998. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>: country report. Analysis <strong>of</strong> economic<br />
and political trends every quarter. London: EIU Publishers.<br />
Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) 1998. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>: country report 2nd quarter 1998.<br />
London: EIU Publishers.<br />
Fenn, P & Veljanovski, C G 1988. A positive economic theory <strong>of</strong> regulatory enforcement.<br />
Economic Journal 98( 393): 1055±1071.<br />
Fubara, B 1985. Scope <strong>of</strong> privatisation <strong>of</strong> public enterprise in Nigeria. <strong>Africa</strong>n Administrative<br />
Studies 15: 199±207.<br />
Hartley, K, Parker, D & Martin, S 1991. Organisational status, ownership and productivity.<br />
Fiscal Studies 12, 2 May: 46±60.<br />
Hutchinson, G 1991. Efficiency gains through privatization <strong>of</strong> UK industries, in Privatization<br />
and economic efficiency, edited by A F Ott & K Hartley. Aldershot, Hants:<br />
Edward Elgar.<br />
Kay, J A & Thompson, D J 1986. Privatisation: a policy in search <strong>of</strong> rationale. Economic<br />
Journal 96: 18±32.<br />
Marsh, D 1991. Privatisation under Mrs Thatcher: a review <strong>of</strong> the literature. Public Administration<br />
69, Winter: 459±480.<br />
Menyah, K Paudyal, K N & Inyangete, C G 1990. The pricing <strong>of</strong> initial <strong>of</strong>ferings <strong>of</strong> privatised<br />
companies on the London Stock Exchange. Accounting and Business<br />
Research 21: 50±56.<br />
Mmobuosi, I 1988. The trend <strong>of</strong> privatisation and the future <strong>of</strong> public enterprises. <strong>Africa</strong><br />
Administrative Studies 12: 211±224.<br />
94
National Center for Employee Ownership Publications. 1986. Employee Ownership<br />
Improves Performance.<br />
Okeahalam, C C 1997. Privatisation and the further development <strong>of</strong> accounting policy in<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>. Forthcoming in Research in Third World Accounting 3.<br />
Okonkwo, I C 1986. Public versus private investment in a mixed economy: an empirical<br />
investigation with Nigerian data. Public Enterprise 7(1): 33±39.<br />
Okonkwo, I C 1991. The Political Economy <strong>of</strong> Privatisation in Nigeria. Public Enterprise,<br />
11, 4: <strong>30</strong>3±312.<br />
Parker, D 1992. Agency status privatisation and improved performance: some evidence<br />
from the UK. International Journal <strong>of</strong> Public Sector Management 5(1): <strong>30</strong>±38.<br />
Parker, D & Hartley, D 1991. Do changes in organisational status affect financial performance?<br />
Strategic Management Journal 12(8): 631±641.<br />
Perotti, R 1993. Political equilibrium, income distribution and growth. Review <strong>of</strong> Economic<br />
Studies 60: 755±776.<br />
Pirie, M 1992. Principles and techniques <strong>of</strong> privatisation, in International privatisation:<br />
global trends, policies, processes, and experiences, edited by O Yul-Kwon.<br />
Privatising Parastatals 1992. <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n Economist 5(4): 5±13.<br />
Pryke, R 1982. The comparative performance <strong>of</strong> public and private enterprise. Fiscal<br />
Studies 3: 82±93.<br />
Sen, A K 1987. On ethics and economics. Oxford: Blackwell.<br />
Svejnar, J & Singer, M 1994. Using vouchers to privatize an economy: the Czech and<br />
Slovak case. Economics <strong>of</strong> Transition 2(1): 43±69.<br />
Thompson, J K 1993. Promotion <strong>of</strong> employee share ownership through public policy.<br />
Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic Issues 27: 825±847.<br />
Veljanovski, C 1989. Selling the state: privatisation in Britain: London: Weidenfeld &<br />
Nicholson.<br />
Vickers, J & Yarrow, G 1988. Privatisation: an economic analysis: Cambridge: MIT.<br />
Vickers, J & Yarrow, G 1991. Economic perspectives on privatisation. Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic<br />
Perspectives 5(2): 111±132.<br />
World Bank 1995. Bureaucrats in business: the economics and politics <strong>of</strong> government<br />
ownership: Washington, DC: The World Bank/OUP.<br />
Wright, M & Buck, T 1992. Employee-buyouts and privatization: issues and implications<br />
for LDCs and post-communist countries <strong>of</strong> UK experience. Public Administration<br />
and Development 12: 279±296.<br />
Yosha, O 1995. Privatising multi-product banks. Economic Journal, <strong>No</strong>vember: 1435±<br />
1453.<br />
95
Book reviews<br />
Can the poor influence poverty? Participatory poverty<br />
assessments in the developing world, by Caroline M<br />
Robb, Washington DC: The World Bank 1999.<br />
As the title states, the book deals with participatory poverty assessment (PPAs)<br />
and more specifically looks at the use <strong>of</strong> participatory techniques in poverty<br />
assessment work. A poverty assessment that uses the PPA research method<br />
gives the poor, marginalised and excluded a say in the making <strong>of</strong> policy. In the<br />
past too much <strong>of</strong> the analytic work on poverty, which is critical to an understanding<br />
<strong>of</strong> the nature and causes <strong>of</strong> poverty, has unfortunately treated the poor<br />
as an object <strong>of</strong> inquiry.<br />
Poverty has become vital to the World Bank in the past decade since it has<br />
reaffirmed the reduction <strong>of</strong> poverty as its central purpose. The Bank has become<br />
one <strong>of</strong> the major agents and supporters <strong>of</strong> the study <strong>of</strong> poverty and has<br />
looked at poverty assessment in a number <strong>of</strong> countries. The Bank has mainly<br />
used traditional household surveys, especially multipurpose surveys that use<br />
questionnaires in order to record a series <strong>of</strong> measurements <strong>of</strong> wellbeing in a<br />
household. As a result The World Bank has <strong>of</strong>ten been blamed for working too<br />
much with a consumption-based definition <strong>of</strong> poverty.<br />
The World Bank has increasingly started using participatory techniques in<br />
project and related work. The study that is reviewed here surveys one part <strong>of</strong><br />
this trend. The author <strong>of</strong> this book, Caroline Robb, shows that the use <strong>of</strong> participatory<br />
techniques in poverty assessment has become a general practice in<br />
the late 1990s. Many <strong>of</strong> the results attained have in some cases confirmed and<br />
in others contradicted the conclusions reached in the older questionnaire-type<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>nus <strong>30</strong>(2)2000 96
national household surveys. The results <strong>of</strong>ten confirm that the poor themselves<br />
see poverty as having many dimensions. What is important here is that the<br />
traditional household surveys and participatory poverty work can complement<br />
one another.<br />
This book consists <strong>of</strong> a summary, three core chapters and various annexes<br />
dealing with technical issues. In the summary the meaning <strong>of</strong> participatory<br />
poverty assessment is explained and the variety <strong>of</strong> outcomes and impacts that<br />
it has had in the world are discussed. Finally, emerging lessons for good<br />
practice are briefly summarised.<br />
As its heading implies, chapter 1 sketches the present status by firstly providing<br />
the background on PPAs. The chapter also elaborates on the meaning <strong>of</strong> PPAs<br />
and summarises the experiences <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> the PPAs by examining the<br />
methodologies used, time spent in the field, number <strong>of</strong> communities assessed,<br />
agencies conducting the fieldwork, cost and year <strong>of</strong> fieldwork. The status report<br />
(in question form) also briefly discusses the three main issues to be considered<br />
when conducting participatory policy research, namely sequencing and duration,<br />
research teams and methodologies.<br />
Chapter 2 discusses case examples to explore the diverse array <strong>of</strong> observed<br />
impacts <strong>of</strong> the PPAs in the context <strong>of</strong> the following categories: the extent to<br />
which PPAs have deepened the understanding <strong>of</strong> poverty; their impact on attitudes<br />
and consequent policy change; and the extent to which frameworks for<br />
policy implementation have been strengthened. Criteria are given for each<br />
impact type and applied at three levels, namely World Bank, country and<br />
community level, and their implications are discussed.<br />
Chapter 3, entitled Emerging good practice, identifies good practices that<br />
should be considered when undertaking participatory policy research for policy<br />
changes. Emerging good practice builds on the impact <strong>of</strong> key variables discussed<br />
in chapter 2 and are clearly summarised for the various levels.<br />
Several useful annexes on PPA methodology, impact and country case examples<br />
are included after chapter 3.<br />
In general, this publication provides a useful summary and survey <strong>of</strong> numerous<br />
PPA experiences around the world up to the present. A particular characteristic<br />
<strong>of</strong> this book is its useful tables, figures and boxes illustrating key issues.<br />
Some objections that may be raised are inter alia that critical challenges facing<br />
97
PPAs could have been elaborated on and practical difficulties such as cost, time<br />
and management skills in meeting principles <strong>of</strong> good practice could have been<br />
more readily acknowledged.<br />
What is clear, is that by using the knowledge gained from the experience <strong>of</strong><br />
previous PPAs, future PPAs can make more informed decisions. Therefore this<br />
publication may be viewed as a starting point for future reflection on the role <strong>of</strong><br />
PPAs.<br />
NAAS DU PLESSIS<br />
Department <strong>of</strong> Development Administration<br />
Unisa<br />
Expectations <strong>of</strong> modernity: myths and meanings <strong>of</strong> urban<br />
life on the Zambian copperbelt, by James Ferguson,<br />
Berkeley: <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> California Press 1999.<br />
If the modernist story <strong>of</strong> development has lost its credibility, the most<br />
pressing question would appear to be not whether we should lament or<br />
celebrate this fact but rather how we should reconfigure the intellectual field<br />
in such a way to restore global inequality as ``problem'' without reintroducing<br />
the teleologies and ethnocentrism <strong>of</strong> the development metanarrative<br />
(pp 249±250).<br />
This important new book by James Ferguson is symptomatic <strong>of</strong> new social<br />
conditions emerging at the end <strong>of</strong> the twentieth century, in <strong>Africa</strong> in particular,<br />
and is reflective <strong>of</strong> new bodies <strong>of</strong> anthropological literature which <strong>of</strong>fer new<br />
perspectives on social processes and human choices.<br />
Ferguson made a name for himself in post-development circles with his The<br />
anti-politics machine: ``Development'', depoliticization and bureaucratic power<br />
in Lesotho (Minneapolis: <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> Minnesota 1994). In certain respects this<br />
book on the copperbelt continues a post-development argument. The face <strong>of</strong><br />
the real future and even the optimal future must be reconceived. The future will<br />
not be one <strong>of</strong> nuclear families, English, increasingly urban consumption patterns,<br />
and the welfare state. Further, the conceptualisation <strong>of</strong> current social<br />
process must change in favour <strong>of</strong> an anthropological and Foucauldian disillusionment,<br />
where the theoretical heroics <strong>of</strong> liberation, development opportunities,<br />
modernisation and national progress (ie, the discourse <strong>of</strong> modernity) are<br />
98
suspended, and the space for social choice and creativity is rather elucidated in<br />
relation to the near-absolute horizon <strong>of</strong> local social and economic hierarchies.<br />
The central theme <strong>of</strong> the book is that the Zambian copperbelt has experienced<br />
a near-catastrophic retreat <strong>of</strong> development and modernisation as conventionally<br />
understood: ``life expectancies and incomes shrinking instead <strong>of</strong><br />
growing, people becoming less educated instead <strong>of</strong> more, and migrants moving<br />
from urban centres to remote villages'' (p 13). And women, rather than becoming<br />
modern housewives, ``were trading in used goods, making smuggling<br />
trips to Zaire or Malawi, or juggling lovers who might be persuaded to help out<br />
with the bills'' (p 167). Yet both <strong>of</strong>ficial and academic interpretation <strong>of</strong> the situation,<br />
and the understanding <strong>of</strong> some on the copperbelt, continues to assume<br />
that the fundamental processes that have occurred and will occur in the future<br />
are processes consistent with the ``modernist metanarrative''. Ferguson further<br />
argues that this interpretive misidentification serves a conservative ideological<br />
purpose and hinders appropriate change.<br />
Can we distinguish Ferguson's argument from an underdevelopment argument?<br />
Is he not providing an ethnography <strong>of</strong> decline caused by world market<br />
conditions? As Ferguson is aware, the situation is one <strong>of</strong> ``disorganised capitalism''<br />
(Lash and Urry) and ``informational capitalism'' (Castells): we are in a<br />
stage <strong>of</strong> capitalism which creates informalisation throughout the world economy,<br />
and which may create zones <strong>of</strong> exclusion which the <strong>No</strong>rth has little interest<br />
in exploiting. If so, Zambia's drop in income, education and life expectancy is<br />
intimately linked to the rise <strong>of</strong> China's economy. I would argue that the argument<br />
diverges from an underdevelopment perspective in that proletarian and<br />
peasant actors, each rooted in economic sectors moving towards greater capitalist<br />
rationalisation, and each galvanised to enter public politics, fail to<br />
emerge in Ferguson's account. Rather, the pressures <strong>of</strong> underdevelopment<br />
impact on a complex web <strong>of</strong> differences located in specific contexts and discourses<br />
on the copperbelt, which must be recursively traced, and which are<br />
highly unlikely to lead to a consistently progressive politics, let alone increasingly<br />
urban/ individualist/nuclear/ post-mythological social traits. In addition, the<br />
reading <strong>of</strong> the situation <strong>of</strong> underdevelopment is systematically social and anthropological,<br />
in distinction to the economism ± and political economism ± <strong>of</strong> the<br />
underdevelopment school.<br />
Ferguson's use <strong>of</strong> recent social and anthropological theory, and studies <strong>of</strong><br />
Zambia ± such as the work <strong>of</strong> Pierre Bourdieu, and the feminist perspectives <strong>of</strong><br />
Henrietta Moore, Megan Vaughan and Jane Parpart ± shows a creative coa-<br />
99
lescence <strong>of</strong> new perspectives in Ferguson's work. Despite Ferguson's theoreticist<br />
tilting at the windmills <strong>of</strong> ``modernity'', much <strong>of</strong> this text manages to reflect<br />
some <strong>of</strong> what is known by ordinary people, and his use <strong>of</strong> new theory seems to<br />
clarify rather than obfuscate.<br />
At the same time, Ferguson indulges in a negative populism which at least<br />
implicitly denies the relevance <strong>of</strong> formal, modern structures such as formal<br />
democracy, government structures and the formal economy, weak though it be.<br />
There is an uncomfortable disjuncture between western scholars illustrating the<br />
pathos <strong>of</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n states, and those scholars, politicians and organisations in<br />
<strong>Africa</strong> endeavouring to take responsibility for these troubled and pluriform<br />
states and social economies. One thinks here <strong>of</strong> efforts <strong>of</strong> CODESRIA, the<br />
efforts <strong>of</strong> the Economic Commission for <strong>Africa</strong>, the OAU's program for an<br />
<strong>Africa</strong>n Economic Community, and the work <strong>of</strong> scholars such as Thandika<br />
Mkandawire and Achille Mvemve who are associated with these organisations<br />
± one even thinks <strong>of</strong> certain political leaders and governments. What is the use<br />
<strong>of</strong> a politics which occludes the terrain <strong>of</strong> government?<br />
PETER STEWART<br />
Department <strong>of</strong> Development Administration<br />
Unisa<br />
100
NOTES TO CONTRIBUTORS<br />
Contributions to <strong>AFRICANUS</strong> are welcomed and should be submitted in English. The length <strong>of</strong> an average article<br />
is 4 000 words, research notes 2 000 words, and book reviews 500 words, but in exceptional cases longer<br />
contributions could be accepted.<br />
<strong>AFRICANUS</strong> aims to be a conduit between the academic debate on, and the practice <strong>of</strong>, development. Therefore,<br />
contributions should reflect<br />
. practice (case studies dealing with practical aspects <strong>of</strong> development)<br />
. theory (debate and reflection on development theory in respect <strong>of</strong> the Third World in general but southern <strong>Africa</strong><br />
in particular) ± in other words, the application and interpretation <strong>of</strong> theory in the Third World and particularly in<br />
the southern <strong>Africa</strong>n context.<br />
Contributions are subjected to peer evaluation. The manuscript should be typed in one-and-a-half or double<br />
spacing. One hard copy and one electronic copy <strong>of</strong> the manuscript, preferably in WordPerfect 6.1, should be<br />
submitted.<br />
This journal uses the Harvard reference technique. This technique involves inserting, in the text, the author's<br />
surname, the year <strong>of</strong> publication <strong>of</strong> the source and the page number(s) on which the information appears. An<br />
alphabetical list <strong>of</strong> sources consulted should be provided at the end <strong>of</strong> the article, containing all the relevant<br />
information such as the author's surname and initials, date <strong>of</strong> publication, full title <strong>of</strong> the book or article, place <strong>of</strong><br />
publication, and publisher. Contributors are requested to follow the format indicated below.<br />
Direct quotes from books, edited contributions and periodical articles used in the manuscript:<br />
``Ignorant <strong>of</strong> the law, without legal advice, competing for employment and services with others in a similar<br />
condition, the household is an easy victim <strong>of</strong> predation by the powerful'' (Chambers 1983:110).<br />
Paraphrasing or indirect references:<br />
Chambers (1983:110) points out that poor households are powerless and vulnerable.<br />
Example <strong>of</strong> a list <strong>of</strong> sources consulted:<br />
Chambers, R 1983. Rural development: putting the last first. London: Longman.<br />
Griffen, K 1986. Communal land tenure systems and their role in rural development, in Theory and reality in<br />
development: essays in honour <strong>of</strong> Paul Streeten, edited by S Lall and F Stewart, London: Macmillan.<br />
Rogerson, C M 1992. Feeding <strong>Africa</strong>'s cities: the role and potential <strong>of</strong> urban agriculture. <strong>Africa</strong> Insight 22 (4).<br />
Contributors <strong>of</strong> articles, research notes and book reviews accepted for publication will receive two copies <strong>of</strong> the<br />
number.<br />
All contributions, books for review and other editorial correspondence should be addressed to the Editor,<br />
<strong>AFRICANUS</strong>, Department <strong>of</strong> Development Administration, <strong>University</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, PO Box 392, Unisa, 0003,<br />
Republic <strong>of</strong> <strong>South</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>.<br />
101
CHECKLIST FOR CONTRIBUTIONS TO <strong>AFRICANUS</strong><br />
(Please photocopy, complete and include with manuscript)<br />
1. Original contribution<br />
2. Of interest to development debate and practice<br />
3. References (Harvard technique)<br />
4. <strong>No</strong>t exceeding 4 000 words<br />
5. One and a half (or double) spacing<br />
6. Sequence <strong>of</strong> headings correct<br />
7. Printout (hard copy)<br />
8. Floppy disc (in Word Perfect clearly marked)<br />
9. Kept own copy<br />
103