12.01.2015 Views

Post merger profitability analysis of shareholders. Evidence from ...

Post merger profitability analysis of shareholders. Evidence from ...

Post merger profitability analysis of shareholders. Evidence from ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Post</strong> <strong>merger</strong> <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>shareholders</strong>.<br />

<strong>Evidence</strong> <strong>from</strong> Europe.<br />

by<br />

Varun Daga<br />

2007<br />

A Dissertation in part consideration for the degree <strong>of</strong><br />

Master in Finance and Investment


Dedicated to my Grandparents and Parents<br />

2


Acknowledgements<br />

The author would like to thank his supervisor, Pr<strong>of</strong>essor John Hasseldine<br />

for the guidance and advice through this project.<br />

3


Abstract<br />

The effects <strong>of</strong> takeovers on the value <strong>of</strong> both, target and bidder firms<br />

have been studied by many researchers. While in the United States there<br />

is extensive empirical evidence on the effects <strong>of</strong> consolidation on share<br />

price movements, the empirical literature remains limited in Europe.<br />

Reviewing the relevant literature suggests that the majority <strong>of</strong> previous<br />

work concludes that the bulk <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s perform strongly pre <strong>merger</strong> and<br />

poorly afterwards. It is subject <strong>of</strong> the Hubris Hypothesis that bidders<br />

outperform the market pre <strong>merger</strong> and that bidder and target combined<br />

value is around zero. Systematically nonzero abnormal share returns after<br />

a particular event is inconsistent with market efficiency. The hubris<br />

hypothesis argues that bidders make systematic mistakes. Modigliani and<br />

Miller stress in their irrelevancy preposition that the means by which an<br />

investment is financed is irrelevant. Splitting <strong>merger</strong> deals into relevant<br />

characteristics suggests that the majority <strong>of</strong> research does not support<br />

this hypothesis.<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> methodology, this study uses an event-study type approach,<br />

in which changes in the prices <strong>of</strong> specific financial market assets around<br />

the time <strong>of</strong> the announcement <strong>of</strong> the acquisition are analyzed. Different<br />

valuation approaches brought up in research and practical approaches are<br />

presented. The data is a sample <strong>of</strong> major European deals <strong>from</strong> 1995 to<br />

2004. Abnormal returns are derived <strong>from</strong> the market model.<br />

The author finds that pre <strong>merger</strong>, companies outperform the benchmark<br />

and that during the event period there is insignificant underperformance.<br />

However, during the post event period, the sample firms significantly<br />

underperform on average.<br />

By and large, the main conclusion is that acquisitions destroy<br />

aggregate wealth. It is found that pre acquisition performance is not<br />

an indicator for post acquisition performance. Several effects are<br />

identified (higher combined bidder-target stock returns for friendly<br />

<strong>of</strong>fers and lower for related <strong>of</strong>fers). The long-run post-acquisition<br />

performance is insignificant for equity to shares <strong>of</strong>fers.<br />

4


Abbreviations<br />

AAR<br />

AR<br />

ARIMA<br />

BHAR<br />

CAPM<br />

CAAR<br />

CAR<br />

GDP<br />

M&A<br />

Ri<br />

RiC<br />

Rm<br />

RmC<br />

NPV<br />

SDC<br />

average abnormal return<br />

abnormal return<br />

autoregressive integrated<br />

moving average<br />

buy-and-hold abnormal<br />

returns<br />

capital asset pricing model<br />

Cumulated average abnormal<br />

return<br />

Cumulated abnormal return<br />

Gross domestic product<br />

Mergers and Acquisitions<br />

Return <strong>of</strong> the firm<br />

Return <strong>of</strong> the firm cumulated<br />

Return <strong>of</strong> the market<br />

Return <strong>of</strong> the market<br />

cumulated<br />

Net present value<br />

Securities Data Corporation<br />

5


Contents<br />

Acknowledgements 03<br />

Abstract 04<br />

Abbreviations 05<br />

List <strong>of</strong> Figures and Tables<br />

Chapter 1 Introduction 07<br />

Chapter 2 Literature review 10<br />

Chapter 3 Methodology 38<br />

Chapter 4 Results 60<br />

Chapter 5 Analysis 68<br />

Chapter 6 Conclusions 90<br />

References 94<br />

Appendices 104<br />

List <strong>of</strong> Figures and Tables<br />

Table 1 Summary performance during the estimation period<br />

Table 2: Summary performance during the event period<br />

Table 3 Summary performance during the post-event period<br />

Table 4 Alpha and beta coefficients<br />

Table 5 Portfolios <strong>of</strong> cash-shares acquisitions<br />

Table 6 Portfolios <strong>of</strong> hostile-friendly acquisitions<br />

Table 7 Portfolios <strong>of</strong> related-unrelated acquisitions<br />

Figure 1 Major European and US deals<br />

Figure 2 Mean abnormal performance<br />

Figure 3 Mean abnormal performance post event period<br />

6


Chapter 1: Introduction<br />

In combination with other trends, such as privatisation and<br />

deregulation <strong>of</strong> financial markets, a large and accelerating process<br />

<strong>of</strong> consolidation <strong>of</strong> public listed firms has taken place in Europe<br />

during the last decade. Analysing investment decisions reveals that<br />

the largest investment decisions that most firms make are<br />

acquisitions <strong>of</strong> other firms.<br />

Figure 1 illustrates the strong growth <strong>of</strong> major European<br />

acquisitions during the last decade. According to the Securities Data<br />

Corporation, comparing US deals and European deals reveals that<br />

US acquisition activity is <strong>of</strong> larger frequency. However, the amount<br />

<strong>of</strong> deals in Europe more than tripled <strong>from</strong> 1995 to 2000 whereas in<br />

the US the amount <strong>of</strong> deals grew more slowly.<br />

Figure 1 Major European US and deals<br />

Conclusions <strong>of</strong> post-<strong>merger</strong> stock performance are that there is<br />

evidence that the majority <strong>of</strong> M&As are unsuccessful. However,<br />

what minimizes the explanatory power <strong>of</strong> the bulk <strong>of</strong> the studies is<br />

7


that, while in the United States there is extensive empirical<br />

evidence on the effects <strong>of</strong> financial consolidation, the empirical<br />

literature remains limited in Europe. Next to implications for the<br />

efficient market hypothesis, the more interesting question for the<br />

European manager is whether <strong>merger</strong>s, on average, destroy<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong>’ value.<br />

Given that corporate managers have two choices <strong>of</strong> growth: organic<br />

growth and growth via acquisition, there are plenty <strong>of</strong> winners and<br />

losers in organic growth investments as well as in acquisitions.<br />

Reasons for the overall failure are various but, put simply, an<br />

acquisition can be characterized in various steps and the source <strong>of</strong><br />

failure can be found in those steps (Damodaran, date unknown):<br />

1.) Developing a rationale and a strategy for doing acquisitions.<br />

2.) Choice <strong>of</strong> a target for the acquisition and the valuation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

target firm, with premiums for the value <strong>of</strong> control and any synergy.<br />

3.) Determination <strong>of</strong> how much to pay on the acquisition, how best<br />

to raise funds to do it, and whether to use stock or cash.<br />

4.) Finally to make the acquisition work after the deal is complete.<br />

Within the acquisition process, this paper aims to shed light on<br />

point three. More precisely, it is attempted to examine whether<br />

major European <strong>merger</strong>s are positive NPV projects. The authors <strong>of</strong><br />

the classical corporate finance textbook, Brealey & Myers (2003),<br />

argue that acquisitions fail because <strong>of</strong> wrong pricing “Some<br />

acquisitions may result <strong>from</strong> mistakes in valuation on the part <strong>of</strong> the<br />

stock market … Why don’t we see just as many firms hunting for<br />

bargain acquisitions when the stock market is low”<br />

Firstly, this paper attempts to answer the question whether<br />

acquisition announcements have a similar impact on share prices <strong>of</strong><br />

European companies. This is done with an event study approach.<br />

The event study has many applications. In accounting, finance and<br />

economics research, event studies have been applied to a variety <strong>of</strong><br />

firm-specific and economy-wide events.<br />

8


Secondly, it is <strong>of</strong> interest to explore the possibility <strong>of</strong> a relationship<br />

between deal characteristics in order to evaluate which indicator<br />

suggests if a merged company wins for the shareholder. It will be<br />

focused on the acquirer, the average loser in the literature, and it<br />

will be investigated whether there is guidance to the managers in<br />

the form <strong>of</strong> statistical patterns.<br />

The dissertation is structured as follows. The subsequent section<br />

provides a brief literature review <strong>of</strong> reports and publications.<br />

Section three outlines the methodology; how <strong>merger</strong>-related factors<br />

influence the bidding firms’ share price and how <strong>merger</strong>-related<br />

performance can be captured. Several studies can be criticized for<br />

their weak methodologies. Also a traditional finance model is<br />

adjusted in order to predict possible abnormal performance. Section<br />

four describes the findings gained during the respective event<br />

windows. This paper then tries to evaluate whether the two firms<br />

are worth more together than apart. Section five provides the<br />

<strong>analysis</strong> where explanations for negative bidder returns such as the<br />

method <strong>of</strong> payments hypothesis are tested. Concluding remarks can<br />

be found in section six.<br />

9


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

Merger – Definitions<br />

Narrow definition <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> according to Sudarsanam (1995) is “…a<br />

pooling <strong>of</strong> the interest <strong>of</strong> two companies into a new enterprise,<br />

requiring the agreement by both sets <strong>of</strong> <strong>shareholders</strong>…” According<br />

to Buckley (1995) a broad definition comes along the lines <strong>of</strong> “…the<br />

corporations come together to combine and share their resources to<br />

achieve common objectives. The <strong>shareholders</strong> <strong>of</strong> the combining<br />

company <strong>of</strong>ten remain as joint owners <strong>of</strong> the combined entity…” In<br />

the following section the broad definition <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> activity is<br />

selected.<br />

In the literature, ‘Merger’ is a combination <strong>of</strong> organisations, where<br />

both the merging companies wish to join together and do so on<br />

roughly equal terms and which “create an organisation where<br />

neither party can be seen as acquirer” (Vaara, 2000 pp.82).<br />

‘Acquisition’ is termed as “a purchase by one company <strong>of</strong> a<br />

substantial part <strong>of</strong> the assets or securities <strong>of</strong> another, normally for<br />

the purpose <strong>of</strong> restructuring the operations <strong>of</strong> the acquired entity.<br />

The purchase may be <strong>of</strong> all or a substantial part <strong>of</strong> the target’s<br />

voting shares or <strong>of</strong> a division <strong>of</strong> the target firm (The new Palgrave<br />

dictionary <strong>of</strong> money and finance, 1992, pp.10). However, in line<br />

with common practice (Chiplin and Wright, 1988), these terms<br />

would be used synonymously.<br />

10


Reasons on Undertaking Mergers<br />

There has been an increase in <strong>merger</strong> activity over the whole <strong>of</strong><br />

U.K. in 1980’s and according to Peacock and Bannock (1991) the<br />

attraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s to be a route <strong>of</strong> expansion can be represented<br />

to three main points.<br />

The first point is that the <strong>merger</strong> activity <strong>of</strong> an existing business is<br />

less time consuming, especially in a global environment. Merger<br />

process may be pushed through in a period <strong>of</strong> weeks or months,<br />

unlike the slow process <strong>of</strong> internal growth, which require detailed<br />

planning, recruitment <strong>of</strong> human resource, trial and error, building<br />

relationship with the suppliers and buyers, establishing strategies<br />

etc.<br />

The second point is that <strong>merger</strong> activity in many cases is a cheaper<br />

alternative, especially when the stock market is in its inefficiency<br />

and market information asymmetry. Another example is when the<br />

target company processes intangible assets like patents, brand<br />

identities, goodwill, which could be effortlessly obtained through<br />

<strong>merger</strong> activities. Moreover, compared to internal expansion that<br />

may cost a great amount in establishing a new plant, <strong>merger</strong>s do<br />

benefit an enterprise in financial concern.<br />

The third point is referred to the region <strong>of</strong> economic opportunities.<br />

The rapid technical change gives a new means to the advantage <strong>of</strong><br />

time possible with <strong>merger</strong> activities. In other words, the longer time<br />

to enter into a market and the more competitors are already<br />

entrenched. In establishing entry barriers, <strong>merger</strong>s allow quick<br />

participation in new technological markets to realise potential<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>its.<br />

11


The author (Peacock and Bannock) conclude that the trends <strong>of</strong><br />

undertaking <strong>merger</strong>s to enhance competitive strategy will achieve<br />

another boom in foreseeing future not only in U.K. but also in U.S.S<br />

and South East Asia.<br />

12


Types <strong>of</strong> Merger Activity<br />

To have a more thorough idea and better understanding <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong><br />

activity, its types must be examined and explained through their<br />

specific characteristics with reference to recent examples.<br />

In particular, according to <strong>merger</strong> literature (Stacey (1996),<br />

Thompson (1978), Sudarsanam (1995), Arnold (1998)), there are<br />

three main types <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s: horizontal, vertical and conglomerate.<br />

Theses differ by the type <strong>of</strong> the involved firm, the benefits sought<br />

and the motivations behind them.<br />

Horizontal Merger<br />

In horizontal <strong>merger</strong> two companies, which are engaged in the<br />

same or similar field <strong>of</strong> activity, are combined. Recent examples <strong>of</strong><br />

horizontal <strong>merger</strong>s are the combination <strong>of</strong> Glaxo with Wollcome,<br />

LloydsBank with TSB, and Sainsbury’s own already Homebase with<br />

Texas Homecare. Main motives behind this type are the<br />

improvement <strong>of</strong> market power as a result <strong>of</strong> the reduction in market<br />

competition, the acquisition <strong>of</strong> a more pr<strong>of</strong>itable firm for its<br />

technological know-how, or the achievement <strong>of</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> scales<br />

as the companies operate in the same line <strong>of</strong> business. A possible<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> this kind <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> is the creation <strong>of</strong> monopoly power by<br />

competitors’ reduction and building <strong>of</strong> entry barriers due to the<br />

assumption that new entrants fear increasing market share has<br />

tendency to raise the <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> <strong>of</strong> intervention <strong>from</strong> regulatory<br />

agencies concerned with competition in the market. Some examples<br />

<strong>of</strong> these government bodies are the “Monopolies and Merger<br />

Commission” and the “Office <strong>of</strong> Fair Trading” in the U.K. (Arnold,<br />

1998)<br />

13


Vertical Merger<br />

Stacey (1996) claims that vertical <strong>merger</strong> is a more complicated<br />

process, as the buyer expands not into his own field but into a<br />

different one. The vertical process can be characterised as<br />

“upstream” or “downstream”. At the “upstream” the entrepreneur<br />

proceeds towards the source <strong>of</strong> his supply, such as supplier <strong>of</strong> raw<br />

material. An example could be a manufacturer <strong>of</strong> footwear that<br />

merges with a leather producer. On the “downstream” <strong>merger</strong> the<br />

entrepreneur proceeds through the channels <strong>of</strong> distribution towards<br />

the final consumer, who may be another industrial user. A possible<br />

example is if the manufacturer <strong>of</strong> footwear merges with a retailer <strong>of</strong><br />

shoes.<br />

Vertical <strong>merger</strong> can also threaten competition as the same with<br />

horizontal. By definition, the firm expands vertically by integrating<br />

the successive stages <strong>of</strong> production-backward towards the raw<br />

material or forward towards the consumer. Thus, vertical <strong>merger</strong>s<br />

are used as a means to control production processes. Suppliers in<br />

this type <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> can raise barriers to entry by reducing<br />

possibilities for potential competitors to participate at one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

integrated production levels (Thompson 1978). Allan (1996) states<br />

that this type <strong>of</strong> expansion is dangerous, because both companies<br />

that merge face the same volatility in the business cycle. Hence, it<br />

increases the effect <strong>of</strong> the cycles on the combined company.<br />

Vertical is a common type <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s in industries where<br />

companies’ actively rely heavily on suppliers and buyers for<br />

example a s<strong>of</strong>t drink company acquiring a bottling company.<br />

14


Conglomerate Merger<br />

A conglomerate <strong>merger</strong> is the combination <strong>of</strong> two firms that operate<br />

in unrelated business areas. Arnold (1998) states that the majority<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s <strong>of</strong> this kind are motivated by risk reduction through<br />

diversification or by the opportunity for cost reduction, improved<br />

efficiency or technical know how <strong>of</strong> other partners in unrelated<br />

businesses. An example is that <strong>of</strong> Sony, which is teaming up with<br />

US investment bank JP Morgan and Japanese bank Sakura to let<br />

Playstation 2 consumer’s bank online using their consoles. The<br />

internet bank combines Sony’s technical know-how with Sakura’s<br />

knowledge <strong>of</strong> Japan’s banking industry and JP Morgan’s expertise in<br />

<strong>of</strong>fering investment advice to clients. Sudarsanam (1995) argues<br />

that conglomerate <strong>merger</strong>s are done in the interest <strong>of</strong> managers<br />

rather than in the interest <strong>of</strong> <strong>shareholders</strong>, who try to avoid closedown<br />

<strong>of</strong> a business and consequent unemployment. According to<br />

Goldberg (1983), among conglomerate <strong>merger</strong>s, there are three<br />

types that have been distinguished. (I) Concentric Mergers - that<br />

are the <strong>merger</strong>s between firms in related business activities. Such<br />

kind <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s is an expansion toward the company’s strengths<br />

and away <strong>from</strong> its weaknesses. (II) Geographic Market-Extension<br />

Merger. This type involves two firms whose operations have been<br />

conducted in non-overlapping geographical regions. (III) Pure<br />

conglomerate <strong>merger</strong>s, which include unrelated business activities.<br />

The advantage <strong>of</strong> conglomerate <strong>merger</strong>s is not only in reducing risk,<br />

but also in the transaction <strong>of</strong> management functions. When any two<br />

firms <strong>of</strong> unequal management competence are combined, the<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> the consolidated firm will benefit <strong>from</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong><br />

the superior management firm and the total performance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

combined firm will be greater than the sum <strong>of</strong> the individual parts.<br />

15


It is a kind <strong>of</strong> synergy that will be mentioned at the following<br />

section.<br />

Cartwright and Cooper, (1992) define another type <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong><br />

known as Concentric <strong>merger</strong>s’ in which the organisation acquired is<br />

in an unfamiliar but related field into which the acquiring company<br />

wishes to expand.<br />

Two other terms, which frequently arise, are ‘<strong>merger</strong>s’ and ‘tender<br />

<strong>of</strong>fers’. Loughran and Vijh (1997) differentiate between these two<br />

types <strong>of</strong> acquisitions. They define ‘<strong>merger</strong>s’ if some <strong>of</strong> the following<br />

characteristics are present: the tone was friendly, the target’s<br />

managers were favourable and the board <strong>of</strong> directors and the<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong> voted and approved the deal. A ‘tender <strong>of</strong>fer’ is when<br />

the tone is aggressive, there was no shareholder meeting or<br />

approval, the word tender was used and the percentage <strong>of</strong> shares<br />

sought was mentioned. Further, Rau and Vermaelen (1998)<br />

believed that tender <strong>of</strong>fers tended to be more hostile transactions<br />

and <strong>merger</strong>s friendly transactions.<br />

Concluding<br />

According to the <strong>merger</strong> literature review, horizontal, vertical and<br />

conglomerate are the three main types <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s, which differ by<br />

the type <strong>of</strong> the involved firm, the benefits sought and the<br />

motivation behind them.<br />

However, it should be noted that in reality most <strong>merger</strong>s are<br />

difficult to be classified into such distinct categories since the<br />

different types <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s may sometimes overlap each other. For<br />

example, a <strong>merger</strong> can be classified both as horizontal and vertical<br />

depending on the partner. This can be the case when a bank<br />

16


merging with another bank owns a company that is also in<br />

insurance business.<br />

17


Theoretical Background <strong>of</strong> Merger Activity<br />

This chapter examines the theoretical background <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong><br />

process, dealing particularly with issues relating to why <strong>merger</strong> take<br />

place, but without making a deep and thorough investigation on the<br />

reasons behind this process. It just provides a reference for a<br />

general understanding <strong>of</strong> takeover activity, since an <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> this<br />

kind is out <strong>of</strong> the scope <strong>of</strong> this paper.<br />

Efficiency Theory<br />

According to Copeland and Weston (1992), the most general<br />

theory, associated with <strong>merger</strong>s, involves differential efficiency. In<br />

theory if the management <strong>of</strong> firm A is more efficient than the<br />

management <strong>of</strong> firm B, and after firm A acquires firm B, the<br />

efficiency <strong>of</strong> firm B is bought up to the level <strong>of</strong> efficiency <strong>of</strong> firm A.<br />

This would be a social gain as well as a private gain and such<br />

<strong>merger</strong>s would raise the level <strong>of</strong> efficiency in the economy.<br />

One difficulty with the theory is that if it carried to its extreme, it<br />

would result in only one firm in the economy, the firm with the<br />

greatest managerial efficiency. Hence according to its basic<br />

assumption there are always many firms that exhibit below-average<br />

efficiency or that they are not operating up to their potentials.<br />

Efficiency also includes the possibility <strong>of</strong> achieving some form <strong>of</strong><br />

synergy. Synergy is the occasion where the two firms together are<br />

worth more than the value <strong>of</strong> the firms apart. If two firms, A and B,<br />

are to be combined a gain may result <strong>from</strong> synergistic benefits to<br />

provide a value above that <strong>of</strong> the present value <strong>of</strong> the two<br />

independent cash flows:<br />

18


PV <strong>of</strong> AB = PV <strong>of</strong> A + PV <strong>of</strong> B + Gains<br />

Where,<br />

PV <strong>of</strong> A = discounted cash flows <strong>of</strong> company A.<br />

PV <strong>of</strong> B = discounted cash flows <strong>of</strong> company B.<br />

PV <strong>of</strong> AB = discounted cash flows <strong>of</strong> the merged company.<br />

Synergy is <strong>of</strong>ten expressed in the form <strong>of</strong> 2 + 2 = 5. This can be<br />

achieved through the exploitation <strong>of</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> scale, where<br />

fixed costs become a smaller proportion <strong>of</strong> greater output, and thus<br />

output can expand at lower cost. In specific, synergy is the ability to<br />

exploit economies in marketing through the use <strong>of</strong> common<br />

distribution channels or joint advertising or join research and<br />

development facilities, especially in the case <strong>of</strong> horizontal <strong>merger</strong>s.<br />

There are also economies in administration, research and<br />

development, purchasing and finance. Efficiency theories provide a<br />

basis for <strong>merger</strong>s to achieve strategic planning goals in response to<br />

a rapidly changing environment. However, besides the basic<br />

assumption that many firms exhibit below average efficiency,<br />

efficiency theories are also based on the assumption that economies<br />

<strong>of</strong> scale do exist in the industry and that prior to the <strong>merger</strong>, the<br />

firms are operating at levels <strong>of</strong> activity that fall short <strong>of</strong> achieving<br />

the potential economies <strong>of</strong> scales.<br />

Information Theories<br />

The information or signalling hypothesis refers to the revaluation <strong>of</strong><br />

the ownership shares <strong>of</strong> firm owning to new information that is<br />

generated during the <strong>merger</strong> process. Bradley (1983) has<br />

distinguished the information hypothesis in two explanations. One is<br />

the Kick-in the pants explanation and the second is the sitting-on-agold-mine<br />

hypothesis. According to the former, management <strong>of</strong> the<br />

target company is stimulated to operate into a higher valued<br />

19


strategy that would lead to the revaluation <strong>of</strong> the company, while<br />

according to the latter the merging activity may involve the<br />

distribution <strong>of</strong> new information or lead the market to judge that the<br />

bidders have superior information. The market may then revalue<br />

previously “undervalued” shares <strong>of</strong> the bidder company<br />

automatically after the announcement <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> activities. In<br />

theory, information that the “target company is undervalued”,<br />

becomes one <strong>of</strong> the motives for bidder to be engaged in <strong>merger</strong> or<br />

acquisitions activities.<br />

Agency Problem Theory<br />

Managers are the agents <strong>of</strong> <strong>shareholders</strong>, and because both parties<br />

are self-interested, there are serious conflicts between them over<br />

the choice <strong>of</strong> the best corporate strategy. Agency costs are the total<br />

costs that arise in such arrangements and they consist <strong>of</strong> the costs<br />

<strong>of</strong> monitoring managerial behaviour and the efficiency losses that<br />

are occurred because the conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest can never be resolved<br />

perfectly (Jensen, 1986). According to Jensen and Meckling (1976),<br />

an agency problem arises when managers own only a small fraction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the ownership shares <strong>of</strong> the firm. This limited ownership may<br />

cause managers to work less vigorously than otherwise, to increase<br />

expenditures by purchasing luxurious <strong>of</strong>fices, company cars etc. or<br />

to make decisions that are opposed to the objectives <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>shareholders</strong>’ wealth maximisation.<br />

The agency problem theory <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s has two aspects. On one<br />

hand the threat <strong>of</strong> takeover may mitigate the agency problem by<br />

substituting for the need <strong>of</strong> individual <strong>shareholders</strong> to monitor the<br />

managers. Manne (1965) emphasized the market for corporate<br />

control and viewed <strong>merger</strong>s as a threat <strong>of</strong> takeover if a firm’s<br />

management bummed in performance either because <strong>of</strong> inefficiency<br />

20


or because <strong>of</strong> agency problem. On the other hand, <strong>merger</strong>s may be<br />

a cause <strong>of</strong> agency problem rather than a solution. This is known as<br />

the “managerialism” explanation <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s and was set up by<br />

Mueller (1987). According to it the compensation to managers is a<br />

function <strong>of</strong> the size <strong>of</strong> the firm, therefore they try to increase the<br />

size <strong>of</strong> the firm further. However, Lev and Huntsman (1983) present<br />

findings that managers’ compensation is significantly correlated with<br />

the firm’s pr<strong>of</strong>it rate. Not its level <strong>of</strong> sales.<br />

Roll’s Hubris hypothesis suggests that the agency problem theory is<br />

not checked by the market control mechanisms. Hubris is a Greek<br />

word meaning “animal spirits”, “with connotations <strong>of</strong> overexuberance<br />

and excess pride”. Roll suggests that managers commit<br />

errors <strong>of</strong> over-optimism in evaluating potential <strong>merger</strong> candidates,<br />

thus bidding more than they should and transferring virtually all<br />

gains <strong>from</strong> the transaction to the target <strong>shareholders</strong>. A study by<br />

Moeller et al (2004) showed that larger firms, which might<br />

reasonably be run by hubris filled managers, tended to <strong>of</strong>fer higher<br />

premium and were more likely to complete a takeover than their<br />

smaller counterparts. Gaugham (2005) further states that research<br />

<strong>from</strong> the field <strong>of</strong> management also supported the hubris hypothesis.<br />

He cites the study <strong>of</strong> Hayward and Hambrick which studied 106<br />

acquisitions and found that CEO hubris was positively related with<br />

the size <strong>of</strong> premiums paid, which was in line with the above<br />

hypothesis.<br />

Fama (1980) mention that the agency problem can be solved by a<br />

good internal control system in which strategic planning and control<br />

should be separated, a number <strong>of</strong> compensation arrangements and<br />

by the market for managers.<br />

21


Greater Market Power<br />

In economics market power is defined as the ability to raise price<br />

above the competitive price. Market power implies that a company<br />

has a greater chance <strong>of</strong> enjoying pr<strong>of</strong>its for a period <strong>of</strong> time as<br />

opposed to other competitors (Gaugham, 2005). Thus, M&A can<br />

enable companies to attain a larger market share and thereby<br />

increase the price <strong>of</strong> their products or services, relative to their<br />

cost. Hence, the desire and drive to gain more market power can be<br />

another objective for <strong>merger</strong>s. Increased market power is not only<br />

confined to the area <strong>of</strong> sales but can also be achieved in the area <strong>of</strong><br />

purchases. However, anti-trust laws curb such intentions <strong>of</strong><br />

companies in gaining power.<br />

Tax Advantages<br />

Another motive for M&A is the possibility <strong>of</strong> availing tax incentives.<br />

A target firm becomes valuable if it has transferable tax losses,<br />

which can be <strong>of</strong>fset against the acquirer’s income. Moreover, higher<br />

deductibility <strong>of</strong> interest and deprecation allowances in acquired<br />

assets can also induce <strong>merger</strong> activity. Furthermore, other tax<br />

incentives like structuring a tax-exempt deal also increase the<br />

possibility <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s.<br />

Concluding<br />

According to the above theoretical issues, some <strong>of</strong> the main reasons<br />

that lead companies into the process <strong>of</strong> merging are achieving a<br />

more efficient management or some sort <strong>of</strong> synergy accomplished<br />

by the exploitation <strong>of</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> scales or taking advantage <strong>of</strong><br />

the information that the “target company is undervalued”.<br />

Furthermore, the threat <strong>of</strong> a possible takeover or an attempt to<br />

22


solve the agency problem can also be some reason behind <strong>merger</strong><br />

activity.<br />

The scope <strong>of</strong> this study is to examine the post <strong>merger</strong> <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> a consolidated company and compare it to the pre <strong>merger</strong><br />

<strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> <strong>of</strong> two individual companies by using U.K. accounting<br />

data. If the <strong>analysis</strong> undertaken later comes up with an outcome<br />

where the former is found to be less than the latter, then this<br />

implies that there is no positive economic relationship between<br />

<strong>merger</strong> activity and financial performance, and therefore the<br />

theoretical issues mentioned above can be perceived as a rational<br />

explanation to the query <strong>of</strong> why <strong>merger</strong>s have been and continue to<br />

be so prevalent. Hence, a short reference to them, as the above<br />

attempted to be, was considered essential.<br />

23


The Effects <strong>of</strong> Mergers<br />

This chapter outlines some <strong>of</strong> the positive and negative effects <strong>of</strong><br />

takeover activity, so hat we can have an overall view <strong>of</strong> this process<br />

in conjunction with the outcome <strong>of</strong> the oncoming <strong>analysis</strong>. This will<br />

help us compose our final comments about <strong>merger</strong>s at the end <strong>of</strong><br />

that paper after having examined them first based on their<br />

<strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong>.<br />

Arnold (1998) argues that one way with which the society can be<br />

benefited by <strong>merger</strong> is if the combination produces goods at a lower<br />

cost as a result <strong>of</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> scale or improved management.<br />

However, he states that <strong>merger</strong> may also result to social costs in<br />

the form <strong>of</strong> monopoly power. For example, increase market power<br />

leads to higher prices to consumers.<br />

Jensen (1986) argues that <strong>merger</strong>s represent a noticeably positive<br />

shifting <strong>of</strong> assets into their best use and they provide the best<br />

mechanism for ensuring that managers act in the <strong>shareholders</strong>’<br />

interest.<br />

However, Ravenscraft and Scherer (1987) have a negative view<br />

associated with <strong>merger</strong>s. They see acquired entities as “lines <strong>of</strong><br />

business” that almost always suffering declining <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> after<br />

merging and Scherer, because <strong>of</strong> this fact, concludes that increased<br />

acquisition activity is likely to be a wasteful thing for the economy<br />

as a whole. Roll (1986) argues that an increase in <strong>merger</strong>s is<br />

associated with an increase in corporate “hubris”, which is not good<br />

for the economy as a whole.<br />

According to Aaranovitch (1975) and Hannah and Kay (1977),<br />

<strong>merger</strong>s are expected to directly affect structure by increasing<br />

concentration in the industry. Authors have concluded that <strong>merger</strong>s<br />

are responsible for at least 50% <strong>of</strong> the increase in concentration in<br />

24


the industry. Increasing concentration infers that market power has<br />

increased, and firms will use this market power to increase prices<br />

and as a result to achieve higher pr<strong>of</strong>its for the firm. Thus, <strong>merger</strong><br />

has a positive welfare effect for the firms that are engaged in it and<br />

a negative welfare effect on consumers, as higher prices will be<br />

imposed on them. However, concentration may not be an accurate<br />

measure <strong>of</strong> market power in many cases, as either a high level <strong>of</strong><br />

import competition or countervailing power may seriously weaken<br />

the merged firm’s power despite evidence <strong>of</strong> increasing<br />

concentration (Clarke, 1984 cited in George et al 1992)<br />

Farrell and Shapiro (1990) by using traditional Cournot oligopoly<br />

theory for firms with different cost structures 1 , show that price will<br />

rise if the merged firm does not enjoy significant lower marginal<br />

costs as a result <strong>of</strong> considerable synergies. Hence, if “outside” firms<br />

do not react and consumers and “outsiders” both lose, it is more<br />

likely that <strong>merger</strong> will increase price. This result is similar to that <strong>of</strong><br />

Williamson (1968, cited in Farrell and Shapiro (1990)), who found<br />

that if the private gains are <strong>of</strong>fsetting, price increases and output<br />

reactions may increase welfare. His difference with Farrell and<br />

Shapiro was that he incorporates the reactions <strong>of</strong> non-merging<br />

firms.<br />

As far as labour effects are concerned, Brozen (1982) claims that<br />

when the U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labour Statistics was asked by the<br />

Temporary National Economic Committee to investigate the<br />

consequences <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s in America Industry to the earnings <strong>of</strong><br />

workers, it had reported that “workers in the plants <strong>of</strong> big<br />

companies have higher earnings than those in small companies”.<br />

Yale Brozen, after an investigation on the same issue, argues that in<br />

1 If a firm occurs between firms with identical costs and the merged business has the same cost then<br />

<strong>merger</strong>s are purely anti-competitive. If private gains arise, they will be solely a result <strong>of</strong> higher prices.<br />

25


1963 the top four firms in 409 industries on average paid wages<br />

15% higher than the wages paid in other firms in their industries.<br />

Another effect mentioned by Jensen (1988) is that takeovers<br />

facilitates exit <strong>from</strong> an industry or activity. For example, major<br />

changes in energy markets have required a radical restructuring in<br />

that industry and takeovers have played an important role in<br />

accomplishing these changes. Indeed managers who are slow to<br />

recognize that many old practices and strategies are no longer<br />

viable are finding that possible takeovers are doing the job for<br />

them.<br />

However, Jensen argues that <strong>from</strong> pushing managers to be engaged<br />

in structural changes, growing equity holdings and the fear <strong>of</strong><br />

takeover, cause managers to behave myopically and therefore to<br />

sacrifice long-term benefits to increase short-term pr<strong>of</strong>its. This<br />

phenomenon does occur when managers hold little stock in their<br />

companies and are compensated in a way that motivates them to<br />

increase accounting earnings rather than the value <strong>of</strong> the firm.<br />

Another effect mentioned by the same author is that research and<br />

development expenditure (R&D) is increasing when the <strong>merger</strong> and<br />

acquisition activity occurs. In 1985 and 1986, two record years for<br />

<strong>merger</strong> activity, R&D also set new records. R&D spending increased<br />

by 10% (to 3.1% <strong>of</strong> sales) in 1985 and in 1986 R&D spending again<br />

increased by 10% to $51 billion (to 3.5% <strong>of</strong> sales), in a year when<br />

total sales decreased by 1%.<br />

Hall (1986) argues that takeover and R&D may be substitutes. This<br />

can be done in two ways. Either by investing within the firm for an<br />

R&D programme, or by purchasing another firm after its R&D<br />

programme has yielded successful results. However, he mentions<br />

that a pre-<strong>merger</strong> level manager may try to increase short-term<br />

26


cash flows at the expense <strong>of</strong> long-term pr<strong>of</strong>its by cutting spending<br />

on R&D etc.<br />

It has been mentioned that acquisitions and <strong>merger</strong>s are one-way<br />

managers spend cash instead <strong>of</strong> paying it out to <strong>shareholders</strong>. A<br />

major benefit <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s, according to Jensen (1986) may be that<br />

they involve less waste <strong>of</strong> resources than if the funds had been<br />

invested internally in unpr<strong>of</strong>itable projects. Acquisitions made with<br />

cash or securities other than stocks, involve payout <strong>of</strong> resources to<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong> <strong>of</strong> the target company, and this can create net<br />

benefits, even if the <strong>merger</strong> creates operating inefficiencies.<br />

Concluding<br />

According to the literature review, takeovers can lead to a declining<br />

<strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> for the acquiring company, affect negatively the welfare<br />

<strong>of</strong> consumers as higher prices might be imposed on them and<br />

increase concentration that is a possible indication <strong>of</strong> the creation <strong>of</strong><br />

a monopoly market.<br />

On the other hand, some <strong>of</strong> the positive effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s are<br />

products’ cost reduction since the consolidated firm produces at<br />

lower cost as a result <strong>of</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> scales, an increase in wage<br />

rates and a decrease in the waste <strong>of</strong> resources. Moreover, they<br />

provide an easy way to exit <strong>from</strong> an industry and lead to an<br />

improvement <strong>of</strong> the research and development activities (R&D).<br />

In case that our research concludes in a non-existing positive<br />

relationship between <strong>merger</strong> <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> and financial performance,<br />

the positive effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s stated above will justify the<br />

existence <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>s even if they lead to operating inefficiencies.<br />

On the other hand, if this study concludes that post <strong>merger</strong><br />

<strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> is higher than pre <strong>merger</strong> <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> then the negative<br />

27


effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> process should affect our final comments about<br />

<strong>merger</strong> activity.<br />

28


<strong>Post</strong>-Merger Pr<strong>of</strong>itability<br />

Corporate <strong>merger</strong>s can occur for many reasons: to achieve<br />

economies <strong>of</strong> scales and scope in production, increase firms’ size<br />

and achieve competitive advantage, increase innovation, achieve<br />

risk diversification and potential tax shields, increase market power,<br />

improve technological equipment and displace inefficient managers.<br />

However, the scope <strong>of</strong> this paper is to give emphasis on examining<br />

the <strong>merger</strong>s in terms <strong>of</strong> their <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> rather than the reasons<br />

they occur.<br />

Prior research into the <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> <strong>of</strong> takeovers has focussed on two<br />

distinct types <strong>of</strong> methodology. The first type has examined the<br />

financial characteristics <strong>of</strong> acquired and acquiring firms before and<br />

after the <strong>merger</strong> activity based on accounting data. The second<br />

method has measured the impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> activity on<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong> returns <strong>of</strong> firms engaged in the takeovers. Both types<br />

<strong>of</strong> research are viewed below.<br />

<strong>Post</strong>-Merger Performance Based on Accounting Data<br />

According to Meeks and Meeks (1981) <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> can increase<br />

either <strong>from</strong> a decrease in real costs or <strong>from</strong> a rise in prices relative<br />

to costs. However they note that since a rise in prices relative to<br />

costs can result <strong>from</strong> an increase in market power consequent upon<br />

the <strong>merger</strong>, a rise in <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> does not prove that efficiency has<br />

necessarily increased. On the other hand, if <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> declines,<br />

they argue that it is possible to conclude that efficiency has fallen.<br />

Singh (1975) compared the combined pre-<strong>merger</strong> <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> with<br />

the post-<strong>merger</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> return adjusted for the industry average.<br />

He used a sample <strong>of</strong> 77 firms and made two types <strong>of</strong> comparisons<br />

between firms acquired and those, which are not. First, he<br />

compared the characteristics <strong>of</strong> each acquired firm with the<br />

29


corresponding median value <strong>of</strong> those characteristics for the firm’s<br />

industry. Second he formed a sample <strong>of</strong> non-acquired firms<br />

matched with the group <strong>of</strong> acquired firms in terms <strong>of</strong> size. His<br />

concern was with the differences in <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> between acquired<br />

and non-acquired firms and with both methods he found that twothirds<br />

<strong>of</strong> his sample had lower pr<strong>of</strong>its in the year <strong>of</strong> the <strong>merger</strong> than<br />

previously. Also, in the first, second and third years after <strong>merger</strong> a<br />

substantial number experienced reduced <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong>. Thus, he<br />

concluded that in at least a half <strong>of</strong> the cases there was a decline in<br />

<strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> after <strong>merger</strong>.<br />

Newbould (1970 cited in Caves (1989)) examined <strong>merger</strong><br />

<strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> for the years 1967-1968 in 38 <strong>merger</strong>s. He argues that<br />

because these <strong>merger</strong>s were horizontal, they should have provided<br />

the maximum opportunity for synergistic gains. He concluded that a<br />

sample realised no gains or very little, and the other half medium to<br />

high gains.<br />

Meeks also investigated the difference in <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> pre-<strong>merger</strong><br />

and post-<strong>merger</strong> activity for the period1964-1972 by using a<br />

sample <strong>of</strong> 233 large quoted companies. He concluded that between<br />

one-half and two-thirds <strong>of</strong> companies in the sample experienced a<br />

decline in pr<strong>of</strong>its each year after the <strong>merger</strong>. However, Meeks<br />

results apply to single-firm <strong>merger</strong>s only, because once a firm<br />

acquired a second company it was dropped <strong>from</strong> the sample.<br />

Cowling et al (1980) also studied productivity changes occurring in<br />

nine largely horizontal <strong>merger</strong>s in Britain; using pr<strong>of</strong>it margin on<br />

sales adjusted for changes in input and output prices as an<br />

efficiency measure. None <strong>of</strong> the nine <strong>merger</strong>s that were studies<br />

exhibited extensive gains in efficiency, and two-thirds showed<br />

extensive declines in the few years following the <strong>merger</strong>.<br />

30


Ravenscraft and Scherer (1989), using data <strong>of</strong> 2,732 lines <strong>of</strong><br />

business operated by U.S. manufacturing corporations, they<br />

analysed the pre-<strong>merger</strong> <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> <strong>of</strong> acquisition targets and<br />

post-<strong>merger</strong> operating results for the years 1955-1977. In their<br />

investigation <strong>of</strong> post-<strong>merger</strong> performance, they used operating<br />

income/end-<strong>of</strong>-year assets, operating income/sales and cash flow<br />

as <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> variables and concluded that the smaller the size <strong>of</strong><br />

the acquired companies is the more pr<strong>of</strong>itable they are pre-<strong>merger</strong>.<br />

For the most part <strong>of</strong> their research there is no significant increase in<br />

post-<strong>merger</strong> <strong>pr<strong>of</strong>itability</strong> except among pooling-<strong>of</strong>-interests <strong>merger</strong><br />

partners <strong>of</strong> roughly equal pre-<strong>merger</strong> size.<br />

Healy, Palepu and Ruback (1992) used cash flow <strong>of</strong> companies to<br />

determine whether the <strong>merger</strong> activity succeeds to improve<br />

corporate performance. According to them improvement in cash<br />

flow returns is an indicator <strong>of</strong> increased asset productivity. They<br />

conclude that if the target company is undervalued before the<br />

<strong>merger</strong>, improvements in cash flows would happen even without<br />

<strong>merger</strong>. On the other hand, <strong>merger</strong>s could be the reason behind the<br />

improvement if new opportunities with existing resources arise <strong>from</strong><br />

the <strong>merger</strong>.<br />

O’Sullivan (1997) argues that even though some event studies<br />

seem to provide support for economic gains after a <strong>merger</strong>, the<br />

methods fail to identify the origin <strong>of</strong> the gains. He states that these<br />

gains may be the result <strong>of</strong> the reasons leading to corporate <strong>merger</strong>s<br />

such as a better management team, tax savings, increased market<br />

power or reallocation <strong>of</strong> resources.<br />

One explanation <strong>of</strong> negative bidder returns can be found in the<br />

methods <strong>of</strong> payment hypothesis. Researchers such as Han et al.<br />

(1998) find that under the methods <strong>of</strong> payment hypothesis the<br />

observed negative returns to bidders are attributed to dominant<br />

31


stock exchange <strong>of</strong>fers in takeovers. Myers and Majluf (1984) state<br />

that, according to the announcement effect, current owners <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm prefer share <strong>of</strong>ferings as bid instrument if the management<br />

estimate shares are overvalued. Han et al. (1998) argue that the<br />

information effect <strong>of</strong> the method <strong>of</strong> payment is empirically<br />

supported. Modigliani’s and Miller’s irrelevancy argument seems to<br />

hold true only under their stringent assumptions.<br />

32


Hostile versus friendly acquisitions<br />

Companies can be acquired in two ways: friendly or hostile. Servaes<br />

(1991) investigates these opportunities. Not surprisingly, he finds<br />

that takeover premiums are likely to be higher for hostile than for<br />

friendly targets. In addition, Bradley et al. (1988) examine this<br />

pattern and explain that, as a result <strong>of</strong> competition among bidders,<br />

even higher premiums may be required to be paid in multiple<br />

bidding contests. Comment and Schwert (1995) add that, in<br />

addition to hostile bidding contests, poison pills and control share<br />

laws are introduced, which <strong>of</strong>ten result in higher takeover<br />

premiums. On the one hand this is somewhat dangerous as, all<br />

things being equal, it will become more difficult for the bidder to<br />

amortise a higher premium as more synergies will be required in<br />

order to justify the higher premiums. On the other hand, Jennings<br />

and Mazzeo (1993) argue that high premium <strong>of</strong>fers are less likely to<br />

face competition amongst bidders and target resistance. Han et al.<br />

(1998) find that tender <strong>of</strong>fers are preferred by the market to<br />

acquisitions. In addition they stress that the market responds<br />

negatively to bids for firms that have made prior bids or have been<br />

involved in competing bids.<br />

Related versus unrelated acquisitions<br />

Nail et al. (1998) attempt to answer the question whether related or<br />

unrelated acquisitions have a better success rate. They conclude<br />

that firms in related businesses are, on average, acting in their<br />

stockholders’ best interests, while those who execute conglomerate<br />

acquisitions are systematically destroying the wealth <strong>of</strong> their<br />

stockholders. Considering the combined wealth effects on<br />

stockholders and bondholders, related acquisitions significantly<br />

outperform conglomerate acquisitions – 6.8% versus 3.1% on<br />

33


average and 6.8% versus 1.1% at the median (Nail et al., 1998).<br />

More precisely, fewer than half (48.2%) <strong>of</strong> conglomerate<br />

acquisitions created positive wealth effects for <strong>shareholders</strong>, while<br />

almost two-thirds (64.0%) <strong>of</strong> related acquisitions were wealthcreating.<br />

With respect to risk diversification in conglomerate<br />

<strong>merger</strong>s, bondholders are <strong>of</strong>ten better <strong>of</strong>f in M&A activity than<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong>.<br />

The size factor<br />

The size <strong>of</strong> the target, relative to the size <strong>of</strong> the bidder, has been<br />

found to be a factor <strong>of</strong> interest in the M&A event study literature.<br />

Asquith et al. (1987) find that bidder returns are greater when the<br />

target is larger relative to the bidder. Jarrell and Poulsen (1989)<br />

also find statistical significance for this factor when they argue that<br />

bidder returns are positively related to relative size in hostile tender<br />

<strong>of</strong>fers. With regard to the methods <strong>of</strong> payment hypothesis, Asquith<br />

et al. (1987) find strong interactions between the relative size and<br />

payment method. They argue in their studies that there is a positive<br />

size effect for cash-financed acquisitions and a negative size effect<br />

for equity-financed acquisitions.<br />

Methods <strong>of</strong> payment hypothesis and the information effect<br />

Another explanation for negative bidder returns, called the method<br />

<strong>of</strong> payment hypothesis, relates to the information effect. Amihud et<br />

al. (1990) ask the question: “Do firms have systematic preferences<br />

for the means <strong>of</strong> financing investments” Bidding companies<br />

typically <strong>of</strong>fer the <strong>shareholders</strong> <strong>of</strong> target companies either cash or<br />

stock, and in some instances both, or the option <strong>of</strong> either cash or<br />

stock. Modigliani and Miller (1958) state the well known capital<br />

structure irrelevancy theory. Under some rigorous assumptions such<br />

34


as perfect markets and no taxes, they come up with their<br />

hypothesis arguing that the means by which investments are<br />

financed are irrelevant for the total value <strong>of</strong> the firm. Reacting to<br />

complaints about the somewhat ivory-tower assumptions, Miller<br />

(1977) extended the irrelevance proposition to a case where taxes<br />

exist. Han et al. (1998) attempt to evaluate the market reaction <strong>of</strong><br />

M&A deals with regard to the method <strong>of</strong> payment. They argue:<br />

“casual observation suggests that firms are not indifferent to the<br />

means <strong>of</strong> financing.” Factors such as agency costs may have an<br />

impact into the capital structure decision process as well as <strong>from</strong><br />

asymmetry <strong>of</strong> information between <strong>shareholders</strong> and insiders<br />

(management), as discussed by Myers and Majluf (1984).<br />

The information effect is further explained by Myers and Majluf<br />

(1984) when they argue that managers will prefer share financing<br />

<strong>of</strong> an acquisition when they believe that their company’s shares are<br />

overvalued. This might be the case if management <strong>of</strong> the bidding<br />

company is better informed about the value <strong>of</strong> the firm (actually the<br />

share) than outside investors. Given that current bidding<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong> attempt to avoid dilution <strong>of</strong> their shares, Amihud et al.<br />

(1990) state that “investors expect this and will, therefore, drive<br />

down the value <strong>of</strong> firms [when the acquisition medium is shares].”<br />

Assuming that insiders have better information about the value <strong>of</strong><br />

their firms, it can be concluded that cash (debt) financing <strong>of</strong><br />

acquisitions will, therefore, be preferred unless its cost to insiders is<br />

excessive. Amihud et al. (1990) find that their data supports the<br />

hypothesis that companies with relatively large insiders’ ownership<br />

are more likely to finance acquisitions with cash than with stock.<br />

Eckbo and Langohr (1989) find that, in bids for control, cash <strong>of</strong>fers<br />

result in substantially higher percentage premiums <strong>of</strong> 73% than<br />

35


equity exchange acquisitions at just 17.2%. Nevertheless, the<br />

payment method not only has an effect on the size <strong>of</strong> bid premium<br />

but, according to Jennings and Mazzeo (1993), also on target<br />

resistance. Both report that the most frequently resisted <strong>of</strong>fers<br />

involve mixes <strong>of</strong> cash and securities. Loughran and Vijh (1997, in<br />

Mushidhi and Ward, 2004) find that, on “the post-acquisition<br />

performance over a five-year period, companies that utilised sharebased<br />

acquisitions earned significant, negative abnormal returns (-<br />

25%) whereas companies that completed cash-based takeovers<br />

earned significant positive abnormal returns (61,7%).”<br />

Empirical evidence has shown that on average, long run abnormal<br />

returns to bidders are negative in share financed acquisitions and<br />

positive in cash financed acquisitions. Abhyankar et al (2005) found<br />

that cash financed <strong>merger</strong> portfolios dominated the benchmark<br />

portfolio and remarked that their results corroborates earlier studies<br />

that cash financed <strong>merger</strong>s outperform stock financed ones.<br />

Therefore it can be concluded that the majority <strong>of</strong> research suggests<br />

that market participants value a cash <strong>of</strong>fer higher than a share<br />

value and act accordingly. With reference to overvaluation, Shleifer<br />

and Vishny (2003) argue that their <strong>analysis</strong> illustrates the role <strong>of</strong><br />

defensive acquisitions by firms with overpriced shares: “using these<br />

shares to buy assets available for p


the 1990s. The share <strong>of</strong> acquisitions that were all for stock rose<br />

<strong>from</strong> 32.9% in the 1980s to 57.8% in the 1990s.” In summary,<br />

Shleifer and Vishny (2003) find that:<br />

1) Acquisitions are disproportionably for stock when aggregate or<br />

industry valuations are high and for cash when they are low.<br />

2) Bidders in stock acquisitions earn high returns, whereas targets<br />

in cash acquisitions earn low returns prior to the acquisitions.<br />

3) Bidders in stock acquisitions are likely to show signs <strong>of</strong><br />

overvaluation, such as earnings manipulation and insider selling.<br />

Shleifer and Vishny (2003) stress that using overvalued shares as a<br />

means <strong>of</strong> payment enhances the claim on capital <strong>of</strong> the bidding<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong>, “and thereby cushions the collapse <strong>of</strong> the shares in<br />

the long run.” They state that this approach would be the reason for<br />

some high flying firms, such as America Online and Cisco, acquiring<br />

lower valuation firms for stock during the 1990s.<br />

Franks et al. (1988) conducted a long-term study, with a horizon <strong>of</strong><br />

30 years, <strong>of</strong> payment methods in US and UK acquisitions between<br />

1955 and 1985. They support the Shleifer and Vishny (2003)<br />

argumentation in their performance study that “target <strong>shareholders</strong><br />

earn a risk adjusted return <strong>of</strong> 30% in all cash, and 15% in all share<br />

<strong>of</strong>fers during the month surrounding the bid.” Not surprisingly they<br />

conclude also that mixed cash/equity bids produce higher returns<br />

than pure equity <strong>of</strong>fers.<br />

37


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

Foreword<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> this paper is to focus on the value <strong>of</strong> assets around an<br />

event and to provide evidence relevant for understanding corporate<br />

policy decisions; frankly speaking, a t-test <strong>of</strong> the increase or<br />

decrease in share price. Event studies have looked at many issues<br />

in corporate finance. To name a few, stock splits, spin-<strong>of</strong>fs, dividend<br />

announcements and acquisitions have been the subject <strong>of</strong> <strong>analysis</strong>.<br />

The first event study is attributed to Fama et al. (1969) who<br />

investigated stock splits <strong>of</strong> public listed companies. In the following,<br />

the event study methodology will be discussed.<br />

Share prices, accounting figures and other measurements<br />

The impact <strong>of</strong> the acquisition on the value <strong>of</strong> the firm can be<br />

measured by examining security prices, accounting figures, industry<br />

production, macro data and much more. With reference to the<br />

above-mentioned discussion and the majority <strong>of</strong> academic results<br />

that stock markets are at least semi-strong efficient, the market<br />

value <strong>of</strong> a public listed company should be worth what its shares are<br />

worth. However, previous event studies have shown that<br />

information about a possible takeover typically leaks into the<br />

market in advance <strong>of</strong> the actual transaction announcement. Hence,<br />

target and to an extent target share prices in the run up <strong>of</strong> an<br />

acquisition related bid, embed some element <strong>of</strong> expectation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

planned takeover, or even the impact <strong>of</strong> a pre-bid buying by the<br />

acquirer. In essence, pre-announcement share price movements<br />

suggest a value transfer for the market’s perceptions <strong>of</strong> synergies<br />

that the deal will be consummated.<br />

38


An alternative approach to shares could be to work with industrial<br />

production or earning figures, as followed by Han et al. (1998) who<br />

measure overpayment in acquisition deals by using earnings-price<br />

ratios. The author rejects this approach. Firstly, the key authors in<br />

finance and in particular in the event study literature argue that the<br />

earnings figure is a noisy measure because it is sensitive to more or<br />

less arbitrary accounting methods (e.g. Fama, 1997). Secondly,<br />

industrial production data is not available for the purpose <strong>of</strong> this<br />

study. Thirdly, historic methodology literature, such as Weston<br />

(1953) and Markham (1955) show that acquisition activity is<br />

statistically significant related to share prices, not to industrial<br />

production. Markham (1955) calculated correlation coefficients that<br />

were statistically significant, but were larger between acquisitions<br />

and stock prices than between acquisitions and industrial<br />

production. Alternative approaches to shares do not seem to<br />

promise better results. Therefore the subsequent <strong>analysis</strong> will be<br />

undertaken with share prices. The approach is to calculate and<br />

analyse the return <strong>of</strong> securities around the time <strong>of</strong> an event.<br />

Event studies in finance<br />

An event study can be conducted in many ways. According to<br />

Kothari and Warner (2004), the focus almost always is on the mean<br />

<strong>of</strong> the distribution <strong>of</strong> abnormal returns. Typically, the specific null<br />

hypothesis to be tested is whether the abnormal return (sometimes<br />

referred to as the residual, R) at time t is equal to zero. They<br />

furthermore explain that parameters <strong>of</strong> the cross-sectional<br />

distribution (e.g. median, variance) and determinants <strong>of</strong> the crosssectional<br />

variation in abnormal returns are sometimes studied as<br />

well.<br />

According to the approach laid out by Weston et al. (1997) the first<br />

step in measuring the effect on stock value <strong>of</strong> an event is to define<br />

39


an event period. Estimation period, event period and post-event<br />

period are defined as follows (derived <strong>from</strong> Campbell et al., 1997):<br />

risk adjustment and expected/abnormal return modelling, the<br />

aggregation <strong>of</strong> security-specific abnormal returns and the calibration<br />

<strong>of</strong> the statistical significance <strong>of</strong> abnormal returns (Kothari & Warner,<br />

2004).<br />

The event period<br />

The different lengths <strong>of</strong> event windows in the relevant literature are<br />

remarkable. Extreme examples are Schwert (1996) who works with<br />

an event window <strong>of</strong> -256 days to announcement and Boehmer<br />

(1998) who works with -10 days to +2 days to announcement.<br />

Usually, the event window is centred around the announcement<br />

40


date, which is day 0 in the event time. According to Kothari and<br />

Warner (2004), Lyon et al. (1999) stress that, while long-event<br />

horizon methods have improved, inferences <strong>from</strong> long-horizon tests<br />

still require caution. The major problem is risk adjustment. Kothari<br />

and Warner (1999) explain that the risk adjustment error is<br />

exacerbated in long-horizon event studies because the potential for<br />

such error is greater for longer horizons.<br />

On the other hand, short-horizon methods are relatively<br />

straightforward and trouble-free. In addition, short-horizon studies<br />

might be powerful if it can be assumed that the abnormal<br />

performance is concentrated in the event window. Mushidzhi and<br />

Ward (2004) argue that shorter event windows (when compared to<br />

most prior event studies) should be preferred to avoid confounding<br />

effects; longer event windows are more likely to suffer confounding<br />

effects. It is attempted to ensure that any possible release <strong>of</strong> preannouncement<br />

date information is caught in the evaluation. On the<br />

other hand a very short-horizon test is less sensitive to benchmark<br />

models <strong>of</strong> normal returns. It is decided to work with -20 tradingdays<br />

before the acquisition announcement up to the announcement<br />

date. This approach is in line with Meulbroek and Hart (1997) and<br />

Mushidzhi and Ward (2004).<br />

The estimation and post-event period<br />

A ‘clean’ (estimation period) prior event period is required in order<br />

to estimate the average daily return for a period. This period<br />

includes days on which no information related to the event is<br />

released. It yields an expected return that takes the risk <strong>of</strong> the firm<br />

into account. Albeit the choice <strong>of</strong> the length <strong>of</strong> the estimation period<br />

is somewhat arbitrary, several M&A publications work with those<br />

one month to one year prior to announcement, suggesting that this<br />

41


period is long enough to filter out much <strong>of</strong> the ‘abnormal’ price<br />

changes.<br />

With regard to the post-event period, Philippatos and Baird (1996)<br />

evaluate acquisition performance during the three-year period after<br />

the acquisition is announced to the media, hence to the<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong>. This long-term approach is criticised by Roll (1986)<br />

who agues: “The bid can convey contaminating information, that is,<br />

information about the bidder rather than about the takeover itself.”<br />

As discussed above, the author rejects the long-term approach due<br />

to possible high degrees <strong>of</strong> noise in the share price. Given that the<br />

author cannot exclude noise completely, but wants to measure a<br />

possible impact on share price performance, an estimation period<br />

and post-event period <strong>of</strong> 250 trading-days pre- and postannouncement<br />

date is chosen. For consistency reasons estimation<br />

and event period should be <strong>of</strong> equal length, here trading-days -270<br />

to -20 for the estimation period and trading-days 1 to 250 for the<br />

post-event period.<br />

Investigated time<br />

A discussion <strong>of</strong> the length <strong>of</strong> the investigated time period is<br />

important because it demonstrates how easy it is to conclude there<br />

is abnormal performance when none exists. Event study literature<br />

usually distinguishes between long-horizon and short-horizon<br />

studies. Much work has been conducted on short-term <strong>analysis</strong> and<br />

acquisition announcement studies seem to vary <strong>from</strong> a daily or even<br />

hourly basis to 30-year long-term studies. This paper focuses on the<br />

time period between 01.01.1995 in order to detect differences over<br />

a sufficient time horizon. The most recent date is the 30.06.2004,<br />

given that post-event share price performance is examined 250<br />

trading-days post-event.<br />

42


Daily versus monthly data<br />

Given that return data is available at different intervals, with daily<br />

and monthly intervals being the most common, the sampling<br />

interval has been subject to discussion in the event study literature.<br />

More precisely, the question <strong>of</strong> the gains <strong>of</strong> using more frequent<br />

sampling arises and power gains <strong>from</strong> shorter intervals have to be<br />

considered. MacKinley (1997) conducted research in this field and<br />

stresses: “the decrease in power going <strong>from</strong> a daily interval to a<br />

monthly interval is severe. For example, with 50 securities the<br />

power for 5 % tests using daily data is 0.94, whereas the power<br />

using weekly and monthly data is only 0.35 and 0.12 respectively.”<br />

Given that there seems to be a big gain in terms <strong>of</strong> power <strong>from</strong><br />

increasing the sampling interval, the <strong>analysis</strong> will be undertaken<br />

with daily stock market data.<br />

The measurement <strong>of</strong> abnormal returns<br />

The aim is to calculate abnormal returns (rather than returns) and<br />

volatility over the investigated time period. Firstly, the predicted<br />

return, R for each day in the event period for each firm, must be<br />

calculated. The predicted return presents the benchmark return that<br />

would be expected if no event would have taken place.<br />

For each sample security,<br />

R it<br />

= K it<br />

+ e it<br />

(or AR),<br />

R it<br />

= the return on the security for time period t relative to the<br />

event,<br />

K it<br />

= the ‘normal’ (i.e. expected or predicted return given a<br />

particular model <strong>of</strong> expected returns),<br />

43


e it<br />

(or AR) = the component <strong>of</strong> returns which is abnormal or<br />

unexpected; it is the difference between<br />

e it<br />

(or AR) = R it<br />

- K it<br />

e it<br />

is <strong>of</strong> interest as it is the difference between the observed return<br />

and the predicted return, measured during the estimation period.<br />

Thus, the abnormal return is a direct measure <strong>of</strong> the (unexpected)<br />

change in share price associated with the event.<br />

According to Kothari and Warner (2004), a model <strong>of</strong> normal returns<br />

(i.e. expected returns unconditional on the event but conditional on<br />

other information) must be specified before an abnormal return can<br />

be defined. A variety <strong>of</strong> expected return models (e.g. market model,<br />

constant expected returns model, capital asset pricing model) have<br />

been used in event studies. All these models use the concept <strong>of</strong><br />

residual <strong>analysis</strong>, pioneered by Fama et al. (1969).<br />

The market model and alternative approaches<br />

The market model has been a popular benchmark and is probably<br />

the most common employed method in event studies to measure<br />

abnormal returns.<br />

However, two alternative benchmark models, the market-adjusted<br />

model, and the mean-adjusted returns model shall be reviewed<br />

before it is decided which model to use in order to calculate<br />

abnormal returns.<br />

In contrast to the market model, the market-adjusted model is a<br />

restricted market model with alpha being zero and beta being one.<br />

According to MacKinley (1997), for some events it is not feasible to<br />

have a pre-event estimation period for the normal model<br />

44


parameters and a market-adjusted abnormal return is used.<br />

Because the model coefficients are pre-specified, an estimation<br />

period is not required to obtain a parameter estimate. MacKinley<br />

(1997) however adds: “A general recommendation is to only use<br />

such restricted models if necessary, and if necessary, consider the<br />

possibility <strong>of</strong> biases arising form the imposition <strong>of</strong> the restrictions.”<br />

Weston et al. (1988) conduct their research with the market model,<br />

the mean adjusted model and the market adjusted model to<br />

calculate expected returns. They find that the three methods<br />

produce similar results. Also Brown and Warner (1980) compare<br />

performances <strong>of</strong> the mentioned three models. They recommend not<br />

using complicated methodologies. “We have presented evidence<br />

that more complicated methodologies can actually make the<br />

researcher worse <strong>of</strong>f, both compared to the market model and to<br />

even simpler methods, like mean adjusted returns, which make no<br />

explicit risk adjustment.” Under consideration <strong>of</strong> expected and<br />

actual returns, the market model yields a better understanding <strong>of</strong><br />

what target share prices should be and aids in determining the<br />

element <strong>of</strong> price movement that is attributable to news concerning<br />

a takeover. Therefore, mean adjusted returns and the market<br />

model are applied in the subsequent <strong>analysis</strong>.<br />

The market model is defined as:<br />

where, for the event window, τ ranges <strong>from</strong> T 0<br />

+1<br />

to T 2<br />

where R mt<br />

is the return on a market index for day t,<br />

is the slope<br />

coefficient <strong>of</strong> the stock and measures the sensitivity <strong>of</strong> firm i to the<br />

market – this is a measure <strong>of</strong> systematic risk, (intercept)<br />

measures the return over the period not explained by the market,<br />

and is a statistical error term. In order to calculate the<br />

45


estimations, the ordinary least squares (OLS) regression method is<br />

applied as it is unbiased and efficient. The regression produces<br />

estimates <strong>of</strong> and , which are and .<br />

The predicted return for a firm for a day in the event period and<br />

post-event period is the return given by the market model on that<br />

day using these estimates. The univariate regression is performed<br />

with Micros<strong>of</strong>t Excel. Properties <strong>of</strong> potential abnormal returns are<br />

conditional on the hypothesis that abnormal returns are zero.<br />

In order to capture share prices net <strong>of</strong> these abnormal<br />

price movements, announcement prices are compared to pre-bid<br />

prices. The possible abnormal return is calculated by<br />

Fama’s approach (1997) is followed, which recommends either to<br />

average abnormal returns (AARs) or to sum cumulative abnormal<br />

returns (CARs). The final step is to cumulate the average residual<br />

for each day over the entire event period to produce the cumulative<br />

average return. The cumulative average residual method (CAR)<br />

uses as the abnormal performance measure the sum <strong>of</strong> each day’s<br />

average abnormal performance. The CAR, AAR and CAAR formulas<br />

are derived <strong>from</strong> Agrawal et.al (1992) and are defined as:<br />

46


It is intended to calculate an average impact on share prices in the<br />

form <strong>of</strong> mean abnormal returns in order to test if the null<br />

hypothesis. Additionally, when applied to post-event periods, tests<br />

using these measures provide information about market efficiency.<br />

This is because <strong>of</strong> the fact that systematically non-zero abnormal<br />

returns following an event are inconsistent with efficiency and imply<br />

a systematic trading rule. In addition, CARs are aggregated across<br />

different time periods to see if anomalies sustain over time.<br />

Statistical significance<br />

In order to test the respective hypotheses and to determine<br />

whether a result is statistically significant, the level <strong>of</strong> significance<br />

and rejection must be evaluated. In order to avoid arbitrariness in<br />

the final decision to confirm or reject a hypothesis, the level <strong>of</strong><br />

significance found in the existing area <strong>of</strong> research is applied. The<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> researchers (e.g. Brown and Warner, 1985; Dodd and<br />

Ruback, 1978) work with significance at the 5% level which reflects<br />

a 95% confidence interval. This suggests an acceptable level <strong>of</strong><br />

error and simultaneously is convenient for this type <strong>of</strong> study with a<br />

random sample.<br />

Sampling distributions <strong>of</strong> test statistics<br />

In order to compare the performance <strong>of</strong> the abnormal cumulative<br />

returns, a test statistic is usually computed to compare the<br />

distribution under the null hypothesis; that means abnormal<br />

performance is equal to zero. The t-statistic on the coefficient iβ is<br />

used to test for risk shifts. The null hypothesis that there are no<br />

47


changes in beta implies the coefficient b is zero. A significant<br />

negative t-statistic indicates a decrease in beta and a significant<br />

positive t-statistic an increase in beta after the <strong>of</strong>fer.<br />

The null hypothesis is rejected if the test statistic exceeds a<br />

significant value, here in the 5% tail region. In order to avoid Type<br />

1 (the null hypothesis is falsely rejected) and Type 2 errors (the null<br />

hypothesis is falsely accepted), a test statistic must be correctly<br />

specified. A correctly-specified test statistic yields a Type 1 error<br />

probability equal to the assumed size <strong>of</strong> the test. The second<br />

concern is power, i.e. a test’s ability to detect abnormal<br />

performance when it is present. Power can be measured as one<br />

minus the probability <strong>of</strong> a Type 2 error. The standard t-test <strong>of</strong> mean<br />

abnormal performance assumes that the mean abnormal<br />

performance for the cross-section <strong>of</strong> securities is normally<br />

distributed. The t-test compares sample means by calculating<br />

Student’s t and displays the two-tailed probability <strong>of</strong> the difference<br />

between the means. The t-test for independent data is (Berenson et<br />

al., 2004):<br />

48


df=N 1<br />

+N 2<br />

-2<br />

where<br />

o M1 is the mean <strong>of</strong> the group with the higher mean<br />

o M2 is the mean <strong>of</strong> the group with the lower mean<br />

o SDM is the standard error <strong>of</strong> the difference between means<br />

o N1 is the number <strong>of</strong> cases in group 1<br />

o N2 is the number <strong>of</strong> cases in group 2<br />

o S1 is the standard deviation <strong>of</strong> group 1, which will then be<br />

squared<br />

o S2 is the standard deviation <strong>of</strong> group 2, which will then be<br />

squared<br />

Skewness and cross-dependence in return<br />

Another criterion for a successful event study is power. Generally<br />

speaking, power is higher with increasing sample size. According to<br />

Brav (2000), specification bias in cross-correlation returns reveals a<br />

serious problem in tests <strong>of</strong> price performance. Particularly longhorizon<br />

tests suffer <strong>from</strong> this bias because researchers “maintain<br />

the standard assumption that abnormal returns are independent<br />

and normally distributed although these assumptions fail to hold<br />

even approximately at long horizons.” The degree <strong>of</strong> crossdependence<br />

should decrease in the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the riskadjustment<br />

approach and increase in the homogeneity <strong>of</strong> the<br />

49


sample firms examined (e.g. sample firms clustered on one<br />

industry). Both factors are taken into consideration in this study.<br />

Firstly, the market model is regarded as an effective method in<br />

order to calculate risk-adjusted performance. Secondly, the<br />

investigated deals are <strong>from</strong> all European countries, excluding<br />

financial deals only. Therefore, the sample should be <strong>of</strong><br />

heterogeneous character.<br />

Evaluating post-acquisition performance<br />

<strong>Post</strong>-acquisition performance is evaluated by the change in the<br />

combined firms’ share price. Mushidzhi et al. (2004) argue that:<br />

“the method or approach for calculating the performance <strong>of</strong> postacquisition<br />

returns <strong>of</strong>ten differs <strong>from</strong> the event-study approach used<br />

for pre-acquisition performance, and includes accounting measures<br />

such as cash flow, operating pr<strong>of</strong>it and cost <strong>of</strong> capital.” Industry<br />

performance is applied also as a benchmark to evaluate postacquisition<br />

performance. However, Franks et al. (1991) in line with<br />

the majority <strong>of</strong> researchers and the above discussion suggest that<br />

“accounting rates <strong>of</strong> return are unreliable as measures <strong>of</strong> postacquisition<br />

performance.” Therefore, the respective benchmark is<br />

the DS European non-financial stock index, again.<br />

The buy-and-hold abnormal returns (BHAR) and the Jensenalpha<br />

approach<br />

The post-event risk-adjusted performance measurement is crucial.<br />

However, actual measurement is not straightforward. The debate in<br />

the relevant literature focuses on two main methods for assessing<br />

and calibrating post-event risk-adjusted performance: the so-called<br />

characteristic-based matching approach (also known as the buy-<br />

50


and-hold abnormal returns, BHAR approach) and the Jensen’s alpha<br />

approach (also known as the calendar-time portfolio approach).<br />

The calculation <strong>of</strong> the BHAR matching would identify the portfolio <strong>of</strong><br />

all non-event stocks that share the same quintile ranking on size,<br />

book-to-market, and momentum as the event firm. The obtained<br />

result on the matched portfolio would be the benchmark portfolio<br />

return. Fama (1997) investigated both approaches and argues that<br />

working with abnormal returns poses fewer statistical problems than<br />

long-term BHARs. Fama (1997) argues: “The reason is that average<br />

monthly returns avoid the problems (e.g. extreme skewness)<br />

produced by compounding monthly return to get long-term BHARs.”<br />

In addition, assessing the statistical significance <strong>of</strong> the event<br />

portfolio’s BHAR has been particularly difficult because the volatility<br />

<strong>of</strong> the event firm returns exceeds that <strong>of</strong> matched firms because <strong>of</strong><br />

event-induced volatility.<br />

Furthermore, cross- correlation increases if some industries might<br />

be over-represented in the event sample (e.g. strong acquisition<br />

activity among technology stocks). Warner and Kothari (2004)<br />

conclude on this point: “one simple solution to the potential bias<br />

due to cross-correlation is to use the Jensen-alpha approach.” This<br />

method is immune to the bias arising <strong>from</strong> cross-correlated<br />

(abnormal) returns because <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> calendar-time portfolios.<br />

Put simply, whatever the correlation among security returns, the<br />

event portfolio’s time series <strong>of</strong> returns in calendar time accounts for<br />

that correlation. The BHAR model is rejected due to two main<br />

problems. Firstly, there is lack <strong>of</strong> power as reported by Jegadeesh<br />

and Karceski (in Warner & Kothari, 2004). The former find that,<br />

even in samples with substantial CARs <strong>of</strong> 25% over five years,<br />

detected in 200 firms, the rejection rate <strong>of</strong> the null would be<br />

typically fewer than 50%.<br />

51


In contrast to the BHAR approach, the Jensen-alpha approach uses<br />

a matched-firm approach to risk adjustment. It has been utilised by<br />

many, including Fama (1998) and Mitchell and Stafford (2000). In<br />

the authors’ opinion identifying a portfolio <strong>of</strong> all non-event shares is<br />

a cumbersome and imprecise approach with high potential <strong>of</strong> error<br />

and therefore will be rejected. Instead, calendar-time portfolio<br />

returns are calculated for firms experiencing an event. Then it is<br />

evaluated whether they are abnormal in a multifactor regression as<br />

follows:<br />

Cross-sectional <strong>analysis</strong><br />

If pre- or post-acquisition abnormal returns are <strong>of</strong> high magnitude,<br />

further <strong>analysis</strong> is necessary in order to evaluate eventual<br />

relationship between mean abnormal returns and firm or deal<br />

characteristics. It is identified that a cross-sectional regression<br />

approach would be helpful when multiple hypotheses exist for the<br />

source <strong>of</strong> the abnormal return. The statistical s<strong>of</strong>tware package<br />

SPSS is used for the <strong>analysis</strong>. In the multivariate regression it is<br />

aimed to examine the association between the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the<br />

abnormal return and characteristics specific to the event<br />

observation. Event study literature <strong>of</strong>ten applies the Fama/French<br />

Three Factor model or the Carhart Four Factor model.<br />

For the Fama/French model the regression is:<br />

R pt<br />

-R ft<br />

=a p<br />

+ b p<br />

(R mt<br />

-R ft<br />

) + s p<br />

SMB t<br />

+ h p<br />

HML t<br />

+ m p<br />

UMD t<br />

+ e pt<br />

where<br />

52


R pt<br />

is the equal or value-weighted return for calendar month t for<br />

the portfolio <strong>of</strong> event firms that experienced the event within the<br />

previous T months,<br />

R ft<br />

is the risk-free rate,<br />

R mt<br />

is the return on a value-weight market portfolio (typically a<br />

stock index),<br />

SMBp t<br />

is the difference between the return on the portfolio <strong>of</strong> ‘small’<br />

stocks and ‘big’ stocks,<br />

HMLp t<br />

is the difference between the return on the portfolio <strong>of</strong> ‘high’<br />

and ‘low’ book-to-market stocks,<br />

UMDp t<br />

is the difference between the return on the portfolio <strong>of</strong> past<br />

one-year ‘winners’ and ‘losers’,<br />

ap is the average monthly abnormal return (Jensen-alpha) on the<br />

portfolio <strong>of</strong> event firms over the T-month post-event period,<br />

Bp, sp, hp, and mp are sensitivities (betas) <strong>of</strong> the event portfolio to<br />

the four factors. Inferences about the abnormal performance are on<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> the estimated ap and its statistical significance. The<br />

estimated intercept <strong>from</strong> the regression <strong>of</strong> portfolio returns against<br />

factor returns is the post-event abnormal performance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

sample <strong>of</strong> event firms. Therefore, in the regression, a p<br />

should be<br />

statistically indistinguishable <strong>from</strong> zero. If not, there must be some<br />

additional risk factor that is affecting the expected return to the<br />

portfolio.<br />

Also Carhart provides a model (Four Factor model) in order to<br />

provide an adequate description <strong>of</strong> expected returns by analysing<br />

firm-specific characteristics. The Carhart Four Factor model uses<br />

Fama and French’s (1993) Three Factor model plus an additional<br />

53


factor to capture one-year momentum anomalies. The additional<br />

term is the price momentum factor as defined in Carhart (1997),<br />

the difference between an equally-weighted portfolio return <strong>of</strong><br />

stocks with the highest 30% returns and an equally-weighted<br />

portfolio return <strong>of</strong> stocks with the lowest 30% returns.<br />

In the past, the Fama/French and Carhart approaches have been<br />

changed slightly for the purpose <strong>of</strong> specific event studies. For<br />

example, Chan et al. (1991) relate cross-sectional differences in<br />

returns on Japanese stocks to four fundamental variables: earnings<br />

yield, size, book-to-market ratios, and cash-flow yield. They find<br />

that the cash-flow yields have the most significantly positive effect<br />

on expected returns.<br />

Regression variables in this study<br />

In order to test possible abnormal returns, factors are tested for<br />

their explanatory power in a multivariate regression <strong>analysis</strong>. The<br />

calculations are aggregate across firms in order to evaluate exact<br />

statistic dependents on whether or not the abnormal returns are<br />

independent or dependent. The author decides to change the<br />

Fama/French and Carhart models in the following aspects:<br />

R mt<br />

is the return on a value-weight market portfolio, the Europe DS<br />

Non-Financial- stock index.<br />

CSp t<br />

is the difference between the return on the portfolio <strong>of</strong> cash<br />

financed acquisitions and stock financed acquisitions.<br />

HFp t<br />

is the difference between the return on the portfolio <strong>of</strong> hostile<br />

and friendly acquisitions.<br />

54


RUp t<br />

is the difference between the return on the portfolio <strong>of</strong> related<br />

businesses and unrelated businesses.<br />

A statistically significant association between CARs and a particular<br />

variable in the regression indicates that fluctuations in that variable<br />

predict fluctuations in AR levels.<br />

A point to consider is the number <strong>of</strong> variables applied. The power <strong>of</strong><br />

the multiple regression declines when including a large number <strong>of</strong><br />

uncontrolled variables. Some variables might come out as<br />

significant; however the power <strong>of</strong> the results will decline. The<br />

problem exuberates when the number <strong>of</strong> observations is relatively<br />

small. According to statistical literature (e.g. Berenson et al., 2004)<br />

it is recommend that 10 to 20 times as many observations as<br />

variables should be included, otherwise the estimates <strong>of</strong> the<br />

regression line are probably very unstable and unlikely to replicate<br />

if one were to do the study over. With 56 samples this requirement<br />

is met.<br />

55


Data<br />

As mentioned above, the aim <strong>of</strong> this study is to test European<br />

acquisitions. The sample is drawn <strong>from</strong> the Securities Data<br />

Corporation (SDC) which includes M&A activity searchable by date,<br />

industry and corporate name. The SDC Tear Sheet provides all<br />

transaction details including target and acquirer descriptions using<br />

the following criteria:<br />

(1) All acquiring and target firms are European public firms.<br />

Generally speaking, the European capital markets are <strong>of</strong> less<br />

importance as equity source in comparison to the stock markets in<br />

the Anglo Saxon countries. Hence some major family-owned<br />

corporations and their acquisition activities are excluded which is a<br />

limitation <strong>of</strong> this study.<br />

(2) The deal value <strong>of</strong> the acquisition is over one billion US dollars.<br />

This approach is chosen in order to ensure comparability between<br />

deals. According to Kothari (2004) the methodologies <strong>of</strong> many<br />

event studies can be criticised as the event sample would consist <strong>of</strong><br />

firms with extreme (economic) characteristics such as substantial<br />

differences in size, low market capitalisation stocks or low-priced<br />

stocks. In these cases, correct risk estimation is difficult. Another<br />

reason for the use <strong>of</strong> substantial deals in terms <strong>of</strong> size is that it is<br />

aimed at measuring the impact <strong>of</strong> the acquisition on the share value<br />

<strong>of</strong> the firm. The power <strong>of</strong> the findings is inversely related to sample<br />

security variance. Kothari (2004) stresses: “the noisier the returns,<br />

the harder to extract a given signal.” In addition, Dimson and Marsh<br />

(1986) (in Agrawal et al. 1992) present persuasive evidence that<br />

measured performance can be significantly affected by the firm size<br />

effect.<br />

56


(3) Financial firms are <strong>of</strong> different natures, which would reduce<br />

power in comparability to non-financial firms and therefore are<br />

excluded <strong>from</strong> the sample. This is in line with related literature (e.g.<br />

Philippartos & Baird, 1996).<br />

(4) Bidders acquire at least 50% <strong>of</strong> the targets in obtaining an<br />

absolute control. The measurement problem induced by the<br />

acquisition ratio <strong>of</strong> target and bidder is the subject <strong>of</strong> a paper by<br />

Jarrell et al. (1988). They argue that, when a bidder is several<br />

times larger than a target, a gain to the bidder equal in size to the<br />

gain observed in the target can be hidden in the noise <strong>of</strong> the<br />

bidder’s return variability. Statistically, the t-statistic for the<br />

bidder’s effect is likely to be much smaller than for the target’s<br />

effect. The resulting data contains a set <strong>of</strong> 239 acquisitions and<br />

tender <strong>of</strong>fers since 1995 where an <strong>of</strong>fer price was identifiable for<br />

inclusion in the finial sample.<br />

The sample was further reduced for the following reason: if the<br />

acquisition <strong>of</strong> the target is a joint venture. In these deals it is<br />

complex to identify a unique bidder-target match and closer<br />

inspection reveals that these cases are rather strategic<br />

reorganisations <strong>of</strong> the target firm’s ownership structure <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

without a change in control structures. Thirdly, if the takeover<br />

commission did not approve the acquisition, the deal is excluded as<br />

well. Also, if the acquisition is an internal group restructuring,<br />

transactions are neither legally nor economically takeovers and no<br />

change in control is involved. Included are acquisitions that are<br />

subject to restrictions, such as the sale <strong>of</strong> certain assets due to<br />

commission ruling.<br />

(5) What further complicates the <strong>analysis</strong> is that the transaction<br />

payment is by no means confined to just cash or shares, but may<br />

57


comprise a mixture <strong>of</strong> the two, complex hybrid instruments like<br />

convertible loan stock, preferred shares and equity warrants, albeit<br />

rarely used. For consistency reasons these deals are excluded also.<br />

(6) Deals are further distinguished by the nature <strong>of</strong> industry. In<br />

order to construct industry groups, each merging firm’s primary 4-<br />

digit SIC code in the year prior to acquisition was obtained <strong>from</strong> the<br />

SDC Platinum database. The first two digits <strong>of</strong> an SIC code reveal<br />

the industry and sub-industry <strong>of</strong> a firm. If buyers and targets<br />

match, the acquisition is regarded as related and vice versa.<br />

The risk-free rate is the three month money market interest rate for<br />

the respective deal and announcement date. For the 25 European<br />

Union countries the data is derived <strong>from</strong> the source<br />

eurostat.cec.eu.int. For those non-EU countries, such as<br />

Switzerland, the interest rates are derived <strong>from</strong> the respective<br />

central bank homepages.<br />

Stock market data is obtained <strong>from</strong> the financial database<br />

DataStream. In the period <strong>from</strong> 01.01.1995 and 31.06.2004 daily<br />

bidding company stock price data was available for 56 transactions.<br />

This is approximately in line with Franks and Mayer (1998) or<br />

Boehmer (1998), who investigated 57 and 46 deals over a nine year<br />

and 11 year time horizon, respectively. One limitation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

commercial source DataStream data is that data is available only for<br />

existing stock market listed firms. Hence all acquired bidders,<br />

delisted buyers or insolvent buyers are automatically excluded.<br />

Therefore the sample suffers <strong>from</strong> survivorship bias. However it<br />

should be noted that, according to a report compiled by the Funds<br />

Management Research Centre (2002) survivorship bias is common<br />

in event studies and authors such as Sharpe (1966), Jensen (1968),<br />

Goetzmann and Ibbotson (1994), Malkiel (1995) and more recently<br />

58


Blake, et al. (1999) had to accept this limitation in their studies. An<br />

alternative approach would have been to search for relevant stock<br />

market data in annual reports and similar publications. Given the<br />

investigated span <strong>of</strong> 10 years and the limited time for this study,<br />

survivorship bias has to be accepted.<br />

59


Chapter 4: Results<br />

Foreword<br />

This chapter presents the descriptive findings and tests the<br />

respective hypotheses. Then the findings are analysed and<br />

compared to the results in the literature review. In a further section<br />

it is intended to explore the possibility <strong>of</strong> a relationship between<br />

abnormal share returns and the method <strong>of</strong> payment factor, the deal<br />

approach (friendly or hostile) and whether the deal was in a related<br />

or unrelated field <strong>of</strong> the bidding firm. The aim <strong>of</strong> this approach is to<br />

evaluate the significance <strong>of</strong> selected M&A characteristics in<br />

explaining the level <strong>of</strong> possible abnormal returns to the combined<br />

firm <strong>shareholders</strong>.<br />

Performance estimation period<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> researchers reports outperformance <strong>of</strong> the acquiring<br />

firm to the market. Therefore the null hypothesis is stated by:<br />

The null hypothesis states that during the estimation period the<br />

bidding firm outperforms the benchmark.<br />

In order to describe the findings in the respective periods, the<br />

approach <strong>of</strong> Agrawal et al. (1992) is applied. Therefore the samples<br />

are subdivided into annual portfolios. The estimation period (clean<br />

period) is characterized by strong bidder performance, relative to<br />

the benchmark. More precisely, the mean return <strong>of</strong> the investigated<br />

56 deals is 19% for bidders, approximately. In comparison, the<br />

mean stock index, the benchmark, performed at 10% on average<br />

during the investigated 9½ years. However it should be noted that<br />

the market performance is characterised by less volatility. The<br />

outperformance <strong>of</strong> the stocks is <strong>of</strong> strong magnitude as, during the<br />

60


year 2000, the 16 samples cumulated by more than 300% stronger<br />

than the benchmark. Given a significance level <strong>of</strong> 5% the<br />

hypothesis can be confirmed.<br />

Table 1 Summary performance during the estimation period<br />

Year N Ri RiC Rm RmC<br />

1995 3 0.09 0.09 0.24 0.24<br />

1996 4 0.30 0.40 0.57 0.81<br />

1997 3 0.75 1.15 0.63 1.44<br />

1998 7 0.98 2.13 1.47 2.91<br />

1999 12 1.22 3.35 1.08 3.99<br />

2000 16 5.02 8.37 1.79 5.78<br />

2001 2 -0.04 8.33 -0.42 5.36<br />

2002 4 0.32 8.65 -0.59 4.77<br />

2003 3 1.06 9.72 0.01 4.78<br />

2004 2 0.73 10.44 0.63 5.41<br />

MEAN 0.19 0.10<br />

MEDIAN 0.15 0.13<br />

STDEV 0.41 0.14<br />

MAX 2.26 0.33<br />

MIN -0.47 -0.24<br />

% winners 69.64 82.14<br />

% losers 30.36 17.86<br />

Note: 2004 was investigated until 30.06.2004<br />

Overall, empirical evidence shows that bidding firms, on average,<br />

suffer <strong>from</strong> acquisitions, experiencing negative returns over the<br />

announcement period.<br />

Firstly, the null hypothesis is formulated:<br />

The mean abnormal return during the event period, derived <strong>from</strong><br />

the market model, is negative.<br />

61


Table 2 summarizes the event period’s individual security abnormal<br />

returns. For explanatory reasons CARs, AARs and CAARs are<br />

reported as well. The average residuals are the sums <strong>of</strong> the annual<br />

average residuals <strong>from</strong> days 20 to the announcement day. The<br />

cumulative abnormal return <strong>of</strong> the analysed 56 transactions in the<br />

event period is -192% cumulated over 9½ years.<br />

Table 2: Summary Performance during the event period<br />

Year N AR CAR AAR CAAR<br />

1995 3 -0,13 -0,13 -0,04 -0,04<br />

1996 4 -0,02 -0,15 0,00 -0,05<br />

1997 3 0,06 -0,09 0,02 -0,03<br />

1998 7 -0,08 -0,17 -0,01 -0,04<br />

1999 12 -0,45 -0,62 -0,04 -0,08<br />

2000 16 -1,36 -1,98 -0,08 -0,16<br />

2001 2 0,29 -1,70 0,14 -0,02<br />

2002 4 0,18 -1,52 0,04 0,02<br />

2003 3 -0,26 -1,78 -0,09 -0,06<br />

2004 2 -0,14 -1,92 -0,07 -0,13<br />

MEAN -0,03<br />

MEDIAN -0,03<br />

MAX 0,18<br />

MIN -0,39<br />

Bidders<br />

Significant 1<br />

Significant No significant<br />

Increases Decreases change<br />

Total<br />

% 29 43 29 100<br />

1<br />

Significant at the 5% level<br />

62


The figures highlight an immense rise in blue chip firm transaction<br />

activity in 1999 and 2000 accompanied by strong stock market<br />

performance in Europe. Amongst the investigated 56 deals, a<br />

notable decrease in ARs during the peak years 1999 and 2000 is<br />

identified. The returns are abnormal as they represent the average<br />

deviation <strong>of</strong> the annual returns on these securities <strong>from</strong> their<br />

normal relationships with the market as derived <strong>from</strong> the market<br />

model. Furthermore, the significantly different numbers <strong>of</strong> samples<br />

in the respective years led to extreme differences in cumulative<br />

abnormal returns. AAR figures are presented to provide a clearer<br />

picture. Negative CARs are indicative <strong>of</strong> under-performing relative<br />

to the benchmark and vice versa. However, this is how the deals<br />

appear and is irrelevant for the hypothesis testing as every year is<br />

weighted equally in order to calculate mean abnormal performance.<br />

Graph three presents mean abnormal returns for the whole sample<br />

divided into annual event windows. It clearly illustrates that in some<br />

periods mean abnormal performance is different <strong>from</strong> zero.<br />

However, the average abnormal return in the event period is -0.03.<br />

A more detailed table <strong>of</strong> individual firm performance can be found in<br />

the appendix.<br />

The findings furthermore reveal that 29% <strong>of</strong> the deals are winners<br />

and 49% loose amongst the investigated deals. Excessive outliers<br />

are common, with 16 transactions featuring returns over 5% and 24<br />

deals significantly underperforming the benchmark during the event<br />

period.<br />

Given the results <strong>of</strong> mean abnormal performance <strong>of</strong> -0.03, the null<br />

hypothesis must be rejected.<br />

Performance post-event period<br />

The null hypothesis states:<br />

63


The mean abnormal return during the post-event period, derived<br />

<strong>from</strong> the market model, is significantly negative.<br />

Similar to the above paragraph, this section summarizes mean<br />

abnormal returns and cumulative average abnormal returns<br />

determined through the market model. The mean abnormal<br />

performance is minus 14%, which reveals significant negative<br />

abnormal performance. The CARs indicates a massive -757% during<br />

the 9½ years post-event period.<br />

Table 3 Summary Performance during the post-event period<br />

Year N AR CAR AAR CAAR<br />

1995 3 -0.42 -0.42 -0.14 -0.14<br />

1996 4 0.70 0.28 0.17 0.04<br />

1997 3 -0.91 -0.63 -0.30 -0.27<br />

1998 7 -0.41 -1.04 -0.06 -0.33<br />

1999 12 -1.08 -2.12 -0.09 -0.42<br />

2000 16 -4.53 -6.65 -0.28 -0.70<br />

2001 2 0.00 -6.64 0.00 -0.70<br />

2002 4 -0.66 -7.30 -0.16 -0.86<br />

2003 3 0.09 -7.22 0.03 -0.83<br />

2004 2 -0.35 -7.57 -0.18 -1.01<br />

MEAN -0.14<br />

MEDIAN -0.10<br />

MAX 0.60<br />

MIN -1.30<br />

Significant 1<br />

Significant No significant<br />

Bidders Increases<br />

Total<br />

Decreases change<br />

IN<br />

% 32 51 16 100<br />

1<br />

Significant at the 5% level<br />

64


Similar to the event period abnormal performance, a significant<br />

increase in the magnitude <strong>of</strong> abnormal performance is identified in<br />

1999 and particularly in 2000. Again, AAR figures are provided in<br />

order to present a clearer picture about the unequally distributed<br />

abnormal returns. Looking at the aggregate performance <strong>of</strong><br />

acquisitions, the economic importance <strong>of</strong> acquisitions with large<br />

announcement losses overwhelms that <strong>of</strong> strong performing firms.<br />

The CAAR, in line with the strongly negative AR is -101%. There are<br />

32% <strong>of</strong> significant winners and 51% <strong>of</strong> deals underperforming the<br />

benchmark by more than 5%. The deviation <strong>from</strong> zero is illustrated<br />

in figure three.<br />

The findings reveal that <strong>shareholders</strong> <strong>of</strong> bidding firms experience a<br />

statistically significant wealth loss <strong>of</strong> about 14% on average after<br />

the acquisition completion date. Given these results and a 95%<br />

significance level, the null hypothesis can be confirmed; there is<br />

insufficient evidence to warrant its rejection.<br />

65


Jensen’s alpha and beta coefficients<br />

Given that, for the event period,<br />

estimated alpha and<br />

beta coefficients are reviewed briefly before abnormal performance<br />

is discussed. The control firm <strong>of</strong> this sample is provided by the<br />

market, risk and alternative returns are presented by alpha and<br />

beta coefficients. The strong pre-<strong>merger</strong> performance leads to<br />

significant positive alpha coefficients. This explains much <strong>of</strong> the<br />

negative abnormal returns during the event period and post-event<br />

period. The following table summarizes average beta and alpha<br />

coefficients, derived during the 250 trading-days pre-<strong>merger</strong> period.<br />

Table 4 Alpha and beta coefficients<br />

Average daily Average daily<br />

Year<br />

N<br />

Alpha<br />

coefficients<br />

Beta<br />

coefficients<br />

1995 3 0.000178 0.25<br />

1996 4 0.000319 0.02<br />

1997 3 0.001068 -0.08<br />

1998 7 0.000570 -0.03<br />

1999 12 0.000386 0.22<br />

2000 16 0.001521 0.01<br />

2001 2 -0.000603 0.00<br />

2002 4 0.000340 0.04<br />

2003 3 0.001295 0.01<br />

2004 2 0.001109 0.27<br />

Note: 2004 was investigated until 30.06.2004<br />

66


Positive alpha values are indicative <strong>of</strong> an over-performance <strong>of</strong> target<br />

share prices with respect to share prices expected on the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

the market model. Beta coefficients stand for market risk. Generally<br />

speaking, a low average beta coefficient indicates that target stocks<br />

are defensive and vice versa. In other words, a low beta stock leads<br />

to a decline in the value <strong>of</strong> in the above equation. Overall these<br />

results closely resemble the trends summarized in the previous<br />

sections.<br />

67


Chapter 5: Analysis<br />

Foreword<br />

After the null hypothesis is tested, the subsequent empirical<br />

<strong>analysis</strong> investigates bidder shareholder abnormal returns and<br />

facilitates comparison with the respective academic literature. The<br />

findings <strong>from</strong> the three investigated time periods (estimation<br />

period, event period and post-event period) reveal extreme market<br />

movements in the years 1999 and 2000. In fact, the investigated<br />

periods illustrate major differences in performance during the same<br />

periods.<br />

Analysis pre-deal announcement<br />

The estimation period (clean period) is characterized by strong<br />

bidder performance, relative to the benchmark. However, the<br />

outperformance is not <strong>of</strong> permanent character. As table 2<br />

illustrates, the bulk <strong>of</strong> over performance can be attributed to the<br />

year 2000. Moeller et al. (2005) conducted research for the US<br />

market but during a similar time period and conclude: “If high<br />

valuations are more likely to correspond to overvaluation in the late<br />

1990s than at other times, it would not be surprising if the relation<br />

between valuation and abnormal returns for that period is different<br />

<strong>from</strong> what it is earlier.” The findings <strong>of</strong> this paper are consistent to<br />

the results <strong>of</strong> Ellert (1976, in Dodd and Ruback, 1978) who finds<br />

that <strong>shareholders</strong> <strong>of</strong> acquiring firms earn significant positive returns<br />

over the seven months before the effective date <strong>of</strong> acquisition. Also<br />

Dodd and Ruback (1978) support that stockholders <strong>of</strong> bidding firms<br />

earn positive abnormal returns before the announcement <strong>of</strong> the<br />

tender <strong>of</strong>fer. More precisely, they report that bidders earn<br />

significant positive abnormal returns in the 22 months before the<br />

<strong>of</strong>fer. The cumulative average residuals equal 11.69%. Although<br />

68


Dodd and Ruback (1978) work with monthly average residuals and<br />

cumulative monthly average residuals, they support the findings in<br />

this study. This is not surprising as magnitudes <strong>of</strong> findings are less<br />

when monthly instead <strong>of</strong> daily data is applied. All things being<br />

equal, monthly data is a less precise measure, as discussed in the<br />

methodology.<br />

These findings are also consistent with Roll (1986), who argues in<br />

his hubris hypothesis that hubris leads to strong pre-bid<br />

performance. Therefore this paper confirms Roll’s hypothesis in the<br />

sense that pre-acquisition performance provides the manager with<br />

power, liability and cash. In addition, free cash flow theory (Jensen,<br />

1986) can be supported in that “acquirers will tend to have<br />

exceptionally good performance prior to acquisition. That<br />

exceptional performance generates the free cash flow for the<br />

acquisition.” These findings suggest that high valuations give<br />

management more discretion, so that management can make poor<br />

acquisitions if it values firm growth more than shareholder wealth<br />

(Moeller et al., 2005).<br />

Surprisingly, Firth’s (1980) study is contradictory to these findings.<br />

Firth conducted studies about the UK market, and UK firms are also<br />

covered in this study. Firth’s (1980) samples suggest that bidding<br />

firms lose up to the deal announcement. He finds that during this<br />

period 80% <strong>of</strong> bidders lose. Firstly, he applies a different<br />

methodology (weighted average standardized portfolios) which is<br />

furher discussed in a subsequent section. Secondly, Firth compares<br />

deals for the period 1969-1975. This period is not characterised by<br />

extreme market performance as during the late 1990s. In addition,<br />

the Breadley et al. (1982) study cannot be supported in that bidders<br />

underperform substantially before the deal announcement. Hence,<br />

their pre-<strong>of</strong>fer performance is inconsistent with the widely<br />

supported hypothesis that on average bidders experience good<br />

performance before making the <strong>of</strong>fer.<br />

69


Except for the fact that the above mentioned studies (except for<br />

Firth’s paper) investigate US deals, there must be other reasons for<br />

differences. In a subsequent section it is evaluated why there are<br />

differences in the findings <strong>of</strong> other authors.<br />

Analysis event period<br />

Anrade et al. (2001, in Shleifer and Vishny, 2001) test a sample <strong>of</strong><br />

3,688 <strong>merger</strong>s between 1973 and 1998. They employ the same<br />

event window as does this study: 20 days before the acquisition<br />

announcement. They find that acquirer firms lose 3.8% on average<br />

over this interval. This is very similar to the findings in this study (-<br />

3.4%) and to Dodd and Ruback (1978) who find a positive<br />

abnormal return <strong>of</strong> 2.8%. However, the results are contradictory to<br />

Moeller et al. (2005) who find that “acquisitions in the 1990s are<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itable in the aggregate for acquiring-firm <strong>shareholders</strong> until<br />

1997, but that the losses <strong>of</strong> acquiring-firm <strong>shareholders</strong> <strong>from</strong> 1998<br />

through 2001 wiped out all the gains made earlier, so acquisition<br />

announcements in the latest <strong>merger</strong> waves are costly for acquiringfirm<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong>.”<br />

Roll’s (1986) hubris hypothesis predicts that, around a takeover,<br />

the value <strong>of</strong> the bidding firm should decrease.His hubris hypothesis<br />

can neither be fully confirmed nor rejected with this sample as it<br />

remains unknown to what extent wealth is redistributed <strong>from</strong><br />

bidding acquirers to target <strong>shareholders</strong> due to lack <strong>of</strong> data for<br />

acquired firms. With respect to the wealth distribution Moeller et al.<br />

(2005) add: “If there are synergy gains, the acquiring-firm<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong> gain or lose less than the target <strong>shareholders</strong> gain.”<br />

The statistically insignificant negative performance in the event<br />

period suggests that decision makers in acquiring firms do not pay<br />

70


too much for their targets on average. This is contradictory to the<br />

Shleifer and Vishny (2003) overpayment theory that acquisition<br />

announcements could have negative abnormal returns because <strong>of</strong><br />

the signal that a firm has run out <strong>of</strong> internal growth opportunities.<br />

This cannot be supported here.<br />

Analysis post-event period<br />

After finding significant negative average abnormal performance<br />

during the post-event period, the underperformance <strong>of</strong> the sample<br />

firms is analysed. It is further examined whether the<br />

underperformance is limited to acquisitions over certain time<br />

periods. Dodd and Ruback (1977) find that, in the month <strong>of</strong> the first<br />

public announcement <strong>of</strong> the <strong>of</strong>fer, the abnormal returns to the<br />

stockholders <strong>of</strong> target firms dominate the abnormal returns to the<br />

stockholders <strong>of</strong> bidding firms. They find combined firm normalized<br />

returns <strong>of</strong> -4.59% after the <strong>of</strong>fer and conclude that this evidence is<br />

inconsistent with the zero impact hypotheses.<br />

On the other hand, Mandelker (1974) provides no support for<br />

negative post-acquisition performance. He concludes: Stockholders<br />

<strong>of</strong> acquired firms earn abnormal returns approximately 14%, on the<br />

average, in the seven months preceding the <strong>merger</strong>.” In a later<br />

study Mandelker had to revise his conclusions when he conducted a<br />

study with Agrawal and Jaffe (Agrawal, Jaffe and Mandelker, 1992).<br />

They find that the stocks <strong>of</strong> acquiring firms perform poorly after<br />

acquisitions. In addition, Langetieg’s (1978, in Agrawal et al. 1992)<br />

findings are supported in that post-acquisition abnormal<br />

performance is constantly underperforming combined firms’ preacquisition<br />

share price movements. Interestingly, Langetieg’s<br />

(1978) methodology is different as he derived abnormal<br />

performance with the BHAR approach, comparing firm performance<br />

71


with firms in the same industry. Moeller et al. (2005) find, in line<br />

with the majority <strong>of</strong> researchers, that: “The combined value <strong>of</strong> the<br />

acquiring and acquired firms for the period 1998-2001 falls by more<br />

than 7%, which is significantly different <strong>from</strong> zero.”<br />

With regard to Roll’s hubris hypothesis, the findings <strong>of</strong> this paper<br />

are inconsistent with the hubris and synergy hypothesis as the<br />

combined value post-acquisition does not equal zero. The losses <strong>of</strong><br />

bidding shares post-acquisition indicate that the firm’s approach <strong>of</strong><br />

growth through takeovers is not or is no longer sustainable or is<br />

expected to be less pr<strong>of</strong>itable.<br />

Implications on the efficient market hypothesis<br />

A finding <strong>of</strong> systematic post-underperformance or overperformance<br />

would be inconsistent with the efficient market hypothesis. The<br />

results indicate that the efficient market hypothesis is challenged in<br />

two aspects. According to Khotari and Warner (2004): “…event<br />

studies focusing on long-horizons following an event can provide<br />

key evidence on market efficiency.” A systematic non-zero<br />

abnormal security return after the acquisition is inconsistent with<br />

market efficiency. In addition, an efficient market is characterized<br />

by stock prices that adjust to corporate signals immediately, not<br />

slowly over a period <strong>of</strong> months.<br />

Given that during the investigated post-deal performance mean<br />

abnormal performance is significantly other than zero (-0.14), the<br />

<strong>analysis</strong> suggests that the efficient market hypothesis is violated.<br />

Over and underperformances are <strong>of</strong> systematic character. More<br />

precisely, there is a market anomaly which suggests a pr<strong>of</strong>itable<br />

persistent trading rule. Therefore, the requirements <strong>of</strong> the efficient<br />

market hypothesis are not met. Although the paid premium is not<br />

investigated further in this paper, Shleifer’s and Vishny’s (2003)<br />

argumentation can be supported. They stress that, if the stock<br />

72


market would reflect all available information about an asset, any<br />

paid premium must automatically lead into a reduction in the<br />

bidder’s share price. Jensen and Ruback (1983) explain the<br />

anomalies in post-acquisition returns with respect to market<br />

efficiency, similarly. They stress: “These post-outcome negative<br />

abnormal returns are unsettling because they are inconsistent with<br />

market efficiency and suggest that changes in stock prices during<br />

takeovers overestimate the future efficiency gains <strong>from</strong><br />

acquisitions.” Ruback (1988) later says: “Reluctantly, I think we<br />

have to accept this result – significant negative return over the two<br />

years following an acquisition – as a fact.”<br />

The differences in event period and post-event period<br />

abnormal returns<br />

So far this study has found that, pre-<strong>merger</strong>, companies outperform<br />

the benchmark that during the event period there is insignificant<br />

underperformance and that during the post-event period the sample<br />

significantly underperforms. More precisely, the mean abnormal<br />

return during the post-event period is -14% approximately,<br />

suggesting that the average firm <strong>of</strong> the sample underperforms the<br />

applied benchmark significantly. Shareholders holding a portfolio <strong>of</strong><br />

the investigated samples lost during the 20 trading-days prior to<br />

deal announcement: on average 3%. The difference between event<br />

period and post-event period can be explained as follows: all<br />

observations are weighted equally, and significantly negative mean<br />

performances and CARs are obtained for the longer periods. Shorter<br />

periods yield abnormal performances that are closer to zero.<br />

According to Boehmer (1998), the small magnitude <strong>of</strong> event period<br />

CARs to post-event period CARs can be attributed to two factors.<br />

Firstly, in addition to the price run-up effects <strong>of</strong> potential rumours<br />

73


and insider trading, there is substantial event-date uncertainty. This<br />

is associated with lack <strong>of</strong> immediate publication requirements<br />

in some countries, such as Germany or France. Secondly, there can<br />

never be full confidence in the announcement date. There is no<br />

guarantee that the source (SDC Platinum Database) has identified<br />

the first publication. Some sources may have published the deal<br />

announcement a couple <strong>of</strong> days earlier. Hence, the exact date<br />

cannot be identified with a precision greater than about one week<br />

(Boehmer, 1998).<br />

Managerial performance<br />

With reference to previous studies, the results shall also lead into a<br />

discussion about managerial performance. The corporate control<br />

literature explains that corporate combinations are considered as a<br />

solution <strong>of</strong> the agency problem since the threat <strong>of</strong> being taken over<br />

focuses managers to maximize shareholder wealth <strong>of</strong> their<br />

companies. Therefore, better-performing firms make better<br />

acquisitions and more value can be created in takeovers <strong>of</strong> poor<br />

performers. Philippatos and Baird (2004) have tested this<br />

hypothesis in an empirical investigation <strong>of</strong> the relation between<br />

post-<strong>merger</strong> performance and merging firms’ pre-<strong>merger</strong><br />

performance. They conclude: “Our regression results indicate that<br />

post-<strong>merger</strong> performance is negatively correlated with the acquiring<br />

firm’s pre-<strong>merger</strong> performance.” This is in line with the findings in<br />

this study and is contradictory to agency theory. The above<br />

mentioned discussion about hubris applies.<br />

Performance split into deal characteristics<br />

Given the significant negative post-<strong>merger</strong> performance, further<br />

<strong>analysis</strong> is necessary. Therefore, the samples are divided into deal<br />

74


characteristics, which are: the nature <strong>of</strong> the deal (friendly or<br />

hostile), whether the deal was in a related or unrelated field <strong>of</strong> the<br />

bidding firm, and the method <strong>of</strong> payment.<br />

Cash versus shares acquisitions<br />

Firstly, it shall be evaluated whether the method <strong>of</strong> payment<br />

provides any market anomaly. A portfolio is created with the<br />

respective deal characteristics. The status quo in the literature is<br />

that cash financed deals outperform share financed deals.<br />

Therefore:<br />

The null hypothesis states that the mean abnormal return <strong>of</strong> bidding<br />

companies is higher in cash payments than in share payments.<br />

Table 5 Portfolios <strong>of</strong> Cash-Shares acquisitions<br />

250 tradingdays<br />

after N<br />

Cumulative<br />

Cash- Shares<br />

Cash-Shares<br />

portfolio, AR<br />

Acquisition<br />

Averages<br />

1995 3 -0.02 -0.02<br />

1996 4 0.27 0.25<br />

1997 3 0.04 0.29<br />

1998 7 0.19 0.48<br />

1999 12 -0.80 -0.32<br />

2000 16 0.90 0.58<br />

2001 2 0.33 0.91<br />

2002 4 -0.01 0.90<br />

2003 3 -0.54 0.36<br />

2004 2 0.06 0.42<br />

Mean abnormal return level: 0.04<br />

75


The results reveal strong volatility during the investigated years,<br />

especially in 1999 and 2000. During these years some extreme over<br />

and underperformance <strong>of</strong> firms explain the results. For example in<br />

1999, the firm Danisco acquired with cash and performed -34%<br />

whereas the share deals <strong>of</strong> Cap Gemini and Finmeccanica increased<br />

by 48% and 36% respectively. On the other hand in 2000 Tiscali’s<br />

cumulated negative abnormal performance amounted to -158%<br />

during the investigated 250 trading-days post performance. The<br />

acquisition was financed with shares, which explains some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

positive performance <strong>of</strong> the cash portfolio in 2000. Reviewing the<br />

findings in more detail does not suggest any persistent patterns in<br />

form <strong>of</strong> industry or other characteristics.<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> mean values, cash-financed acquisitions produce slightly<br />

higher returns to share <strong>of</strong>fers. Given a significance level <strong>of</strong> 5%,<br />

mean abnormal returns are zero. Therefore, the null hypothesis is<br />

rejected. This result is not in line with the majority <strong>of</strong> results <strong>of</strong><br />

studies on the impact <strong>of</strong> the methods <strong>of</strong> payment. Therefore, the<br />

argument cannot be supported that, as most <strong>of</strong> the<br />

M&A studies find, market participants value a cash <strong>of</strong>fer higher than<br />

a share value. For example, Loughran and Vijh (1997, in Mushidhi<br />

and Ward, 2004) present their results in the form <strong>of</strong> CARs and<br />

found that, on the post-acquisition performance over a five-year<br />

period, companies that utilized share-based acquisitions earned<br />

significant, negative abnormal returns (-25%), whereas companies<br />

that completed cash-based takeovers earned significant positive<br />

abnormal returns (61.7%). Also Moeller et al. (2005) find that<br />

equity is used more <strong>of</strong>ten with large loss deals than with other<br />

deals. In the literature (e.g. Myers and Majluf, 1984), there is an<br />

excessive discussion <strong>of</strong> the means <strong>of</strong> payment in takeovers. An<br />

adverse selection problem is associated with the use <strong>of</strong> equity as a<br />

method <strong>of</strong> payment. Shleifer and Vishny (2003) stress in their<br />

overvaluation hypothesis that the market perceives that the firm<br />

76


has no investment opportunities and will therefore reduce its value.<br />

If this would be the case, then this were different <strong>from</strong> Myers and<br />

Majluf (1984) theory that the signal comes form investment policy<br />

rather than <strong>from</strong> capital structure. However, Jensen (1988) stresses<br />

that cash <strong>of</strong>fers may reveal that the firm has cash in excess <strong>of</strong> its<br />

internal investment needs, and is likely to squander that cash on<br />

poor investments should the bid fail. According to Bhagat et al.<br />

(2004), an alternative explanation is that cash acquisitions indicate<br />

strong management that is willing to commit itself to discipline in<br />

future investments. Given the insignificant change in value for cash<br />

and equity bidders, none <strong>of</strong> those theories can be supported here.<br />

Modigliani and Miller (1958) state that the means by which<br />

investments are financed are irrelevant for the value <strong>of</strong> the firm. In<br />

their world, management is driven purely by a desire to maximize<br />

shareholder wealth by investing in positive NPV projects. According<br />

to the theory, managers <strong>of</strong> bidding firms cannot increase the value<br />

<strong>of</strong> their firms by paying for their targets with cash rather than by<br />

<strong>of</strong>fering shares. Interpreting the results suggests that the method <strong>of</strong><br />

payment is irrelevant to the success <strong>of</strong> the acquisition. In other<br />

words, cash paid deals do not significantly outperform share paid<br />

deals and vice versa. This also suggests that the results are<br />

contradictory to the Myers and Majluf (1984) Signalling Theory. The<br />

theory suggests that the long-run acquisition performance is worse<br />

for deals financed by equity rather than cash.<br />

Another important implication <strong>of</strong> this finding is the Shleifer and<br />

Vishny (2003) overvaluation hypothesis. Shleifer and Vishny (2003)<br />

explain that overvalued firms buy undervalued firms. So-called<br />

acquisition waves with stock would occur as stock <strong>of</strong> bidders is<br />

overvalued as a purchase instrument. They argue that this is<br />

“because some managers care only for the short-run market price”.<br />

If bidders’ stock would be overvalued, there should be a pattern<br />

that the share price <strong>of</strong> bidding firms acquiring stock should decrease<br />

77


post-acquisition in comparison to cash-financed deals. On the other<br />

hand, target <strong>shareholders</strong>, acquired by overvalued shares should<br />

increase in value (as explained by Roll’s hubris hypothesis). For<br />

example, Jensen and Ruback (1983) report an average excess<br />

return <strong>of</strong> 30% to target stockholders in successful tender <strong>of</strong>fers and<br />

20% to target stockholders in successful acquisitions. However, this<br />

cannot be supported here. Therefore, the evidence in this study is<br />

inconsistent with the adverse selection theory’s implication that the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> equity is an adverse indicator <strong>of</strong> firm value.<br />

Hostile versus friendly acquisitions<br />

As reported above, the status quo in the literature is that hostile<br />

deals outperform friendly deals. Therefore:<br />

The null hypothesis states that the mean abnormal return <strong>of</strong> bidding<br />

companies is higher in hostile acquisitions than in friendly<br />

acquisitions.<br />

Table 6 Portfolios <strong>of</strong> hostile-friendly acquisitions<br />

250 tradingdays<br />

after N<br />

Cumulated<br />

Hostile-Friendly,<br />

Hostile-Friendly<br />

(ARt)<br />

Acquisition<br />

Averages<br />

1995 3 0.55 0.55<br />

1996 4 -0.56 -0.01<br />

1997 3 0.47 0.46<br />

1998 7 -0.74 -0.28<br />

1999 12 -0.31 -0.59<br />

2000 16 0.21 -0.38<br />

2001 2 0.23 -0.16<br />

2002 4 0.64 0.48<br />

78


2003 3 -1.18 -0.70<br />

2004 2 -0.06 -0.76<br />

Mean abnormal return level: -0.08<br />

With reference to Table 7, hostile deals significantly underperform<br />

friendly deals. The findings are characterized by strong volatility in<br />

the magnitude <strong>of</strong> performance. Although there is a statistically<br />

significant underperformance, the results do not suggest any<br />

promising trading rule. In other words, the results do not predict<br />

any hostile or share performance in subsequent years with<br />

confidence.<br />

The literature suggests two contradictory explanations for the<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> hostile and friendly deals. One school <strong>of</strong> thought<br />

argues that hostile bids are preferred as the hostile acquisition<br />

allows removing bad management. On the other hand, friendly<br />

<strong>of</strong>fers are perceived as opportunity to exploit business synergies.<br />

The results are contradictory to those <strong>of</strong> Bhagat et al. (2004), who<br />

identify higher combined bidder-target returns for hostile <strong>of</strong>fers.<br />

Also Cosh and Guest (in Bhagat et al., 2004) find that bidders share<br />

returns in hostile takeovers’ are significantly high. They furthermore<br />

find that friendly takeovers result in significantly negative long run<br />

share returns, which is contradictory to this study. Moeller et al.<br />

(2005) analyse the relationship between the size <strong>of</strong> bidder and<br />

target and hostile and friendly deal patterns. They find that: “large<br />

loss deals are more likely to be hostile and more likely to be tender<br />

<strong>of</strong>fers than other transactions, but the fraction <strong>of</strong> large loss deals<br />

that are tender <strong>of</strong>fers or hostile is small enough that these deals’<br />

characteristics seem unlikely explanations.”<br />

Bhagat, et al. (2004) furthermore explain that: “On average the<br />

market revises upward (downward) its stand/alone valuation <strong>of</strong><br />

bidders that make hostile (friendly) bids.” This would suggest that<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong> interpret hostile bids as indicating that the bidder has<br />

79


strong cash flow prospects as a stand-alone equity, and interpreting<br />

friendly bids as indicating agency problems. In addition, the same<br />

authors argue that the negative revelation <strong>of</strong> friendly bidders and<br />

the positive revelation about hostile bidders can be explained by the<br />

fact that hostile <strong>of</strong>fers are more likely to be cash and friendly <strong>of</strong>fers<br />

more prone to be equity paid deals.<br />

Related versus unrelated acquisitions<br />

Another subject <strong>of</strong> <strong>analysis</strong> is if the bidder and target industry<br />

provide guidance for successful and unsuccessful acquisitions.<br />

The null hypothesis states that the mean abnormal return <strong>of</strong> bidding<br />

companies is higher in related than in unrelated industry fields.<br />

Table 7 Portfolios <strong>of</strong> Related-Unrelated acquisitions<br />

Related-<br />

250 days after<br />

Related-<br />

Unrelated,<br />

Acquisition N<br />

Unrelated (AR) Cumulated<br />

Completition<br />

Averages<br />

1995 3 0.55 0.55<br />

1996 4 0.47 1.02<br />

1997 3 0.04 1.06<br />

1998 7 0.58 1.64<br />

1999 12 -1.00 0.64<br />

2000 16 -1.76 -1.12<br />

2001 2 -0.22 -1.35<br />

2002 4 -0.93 -2.28<br />

2003 3 0.55 -1.73<br />

2004 2 -0.06 -1.79<br />

Mean abnormal return level: -0.18<br />

80


For the combined firm value the mean abnormal returns reveal<br />

statistical significant underperformance for the related-unrelated<br />

portfolio. During the 250 trading-days post-deal, the related<br />

portfolios underperform the unrelated portfolios by 17%<br />

approximately. Therefore, the null hypothesis must be rejected.<br />

These findings are in line with Moeller et al. (2005) who report that<br />

the acquisitions in their large loss deal sample are more likely to be<br />

within the acquirer’s industry than are the other acquisitions. The<br />

findings <strong>of</strong> this study and the very recent Moeller et al. (2005)<br />

results are somewhat surprising as the majority <strong>of</strong> previous<br />

research suggests that related <strong>merger</strong>s outperform unrelated<br />

<strong>merger</strong>s. For example, Noah et al. (1998) identify lower combined<br />

bids for diversifying <strong>of</strong>fers. Hence, related acquisitions outperform<br />

unrelated acquisitions. The general explanation is that substantial<br />

negative cumulative performance <strong>of</strong> unrelated acquisitions can be<br />

attributed to the lack <strong>of</strong> capabilities <strong>of</strong> acquiring firms’<br />

management. Furthermore, a signal would be given to the market<br />

about the quality <strong>of</strong> the bidder’s investment opportunities or<br />

management, rather than about the advantages <strong>of</strong> the combination,<br />

that lead to lower returns in diversifying transactions. However, the<br />

results <strong>of</strong> this study do not support the theory that investors<br />

perceive diversifying acquisitions as poor investments or that<br />

management is prone to agency problems as investors do not<br />

believe that management is familiar with the target industry (as<br />

stressed by Jensen, 1986). The agency theory <strong>of</strong> diversification<br />

suggests both lower true value improvements, and certainly lower<br />

bidder returns, in cross-industry transactions than same-industry<br />

transactions. A bulk <strong>of</strong> literature explains why diversifying<br />

acquisitions are associated with more bidder agency problems.<br />

Nevertheless the findings are also contradictory to the Moeller et al.<br />

(2003 a, b) study where diversification is found to be insignificant<br />

as a predictor <strong>of</strong> bidder announcement period returns in public<br />

81


announcements. However, it should be noted that the bulk <strong>of</strong><br />

underperformance occurred in 2000. Extreme stock market<br />

performance and, generally speaking, an increase in diversification<br />

attempts might have contributed to this result. Anecdotal evidence<br />

suggest that during strong declines in share prices as during 2000-<br />

2001 investors prefer less risky financial assets, look for financial<br />

synergies and invest in diversified firms in order to lower individual<br />

business risk. In addition, the rise and fall <strong>of</strong> some industries during<br />

this period made the investor looking for companies <strong>of</strong> substantial<br />

size. This might be an indicator for the strong performance <strong>of</strong><br />

unrelated to related companies but is by no means exhaustive. A<br />

more sophisticated <strong>analysis</strong> is impossible due to lack <strong>of</strong> reliable<br />

data.<br />

Cross sectional <strong>analysis</strong><br />

In the last section deals were further broken down into specific<br />

characteristics in order to present a more differentiated picture. The<br />

following section is designed in order to investigate whether<br />

characteristic ratios have a direct effect on the levels <strong>of</strong> abnormal<br />

return. It is intended to determine the most influential variable.<br />

Particularly, the strong post-event abnormal performance needs<br />

further investigation. Therefore, the post-event window abnormal<br />

returns (dependent variable) in time (t) will be related to firm<br />

characteristics. For this purpose the author modifies the<br />

multivariate regression approach, based on the Fama and French<br />

(1993) three factor model. Abnormal returns are regressed on firm<br />

characteristics expected to affect the return <strong>of</strong> the combined firm in<br />

the post-event period. Specifically, equity/shares, hostile/friendly<br />

and related/unrelated are tested for their explanatory power<br />

(independent variables). The degree <strong>of</strong> dependence is measured by<br />

the correlation coefficient between the input and response variable.<br />

82


Details <strong>of</strong> the regression <strong>analysis</strong> can be found in the appendix,<br />

together with corresponding t-statistics.<br />

Firstly, it is attempted to evaluate how well the model fits the data.<br />

The degree to which two or more predictors (independent or X<br />

variables) are related to the dependent (Y) variable is expressed by<br />

the correlation coefficient R, which is the square root <strong>of</strong> R-square.<br />

The R2 is 0.77, indicating that 77% <strong>of</strong> the variance <strong>of</strong> the abnormal<br />

returns can be explained by the three independent variables. An R-<br />

square <strong>of</strong> 0.77 indicates that the variability <strong>of</strong> the Y values around<br />

the regression line is 1-0.77 times the original variance; remaining<br />

is 23% <strong>of</strong> residual variability. Ideally, one would like to explain most<br />

if not all <strong>of</strong> the original variability. Given the independence and<br />

possible noise in the data, this result is sufficient in order to explain<br />

a major part <strong>of</strong> the abnormal returns.<br />

The sample statistic is associated with a p-value (Sig) <strong>of</strong> 0.024.<br />

Theoretically, this means that risk rejecting the null hypothesis (R2<br />

=O), although it is true, is less than .05. In terms <strong>of</strong> variables in the<br />

equation, the related-unrelated beta is <strong>of</strong> the biggest magnitude,<br />

being 1.43 with a corresponding t-statistic <strong>of</strong> 3.69. Given a positive<br />

beta coefficient, the relationship <strong>of</strong> related-unrelated with the<br />

abnormal return variable is positive. This is followed by cash-shares<br />

with -1.05 with a corresponding t-statistic <strong>of</strong> -1.63 and a weak beta<br />

hostile-friendly <strong>of</strong> 0.420 (0.788). In fact there is no statistical<br />

significance in the hostile-friendly and weak significance in the cashshares<br />

t-statistic. The weak t-statistics do not warrant further<br />

investigation in order to test for the most influential factor.<br />

Therefore the intended significance test in the form <strong>of</strong> Partial<br />

Differentiation is not conducted. During the post-event period the<br />

tests suggest a positive relationship between the hostile minus<br />

friendly portfolio and the related minus unrelated portfolio. The<br />

cash-shares portfolio is<br />

83


characterized by a negative relationship. The high magnitude <strong>of</strong> t-<br />

statistics for the related-unrelated portfolio is consistent with Jensen<br />

(1986) who reports that “The t-statistics are actually higher in<br />

magnitude for non-conglomerate acquisitions, even though they<br />

occur with lower frequency than conglomerate acquisitions in our<br />

sample.”<br />

Reasons for deviations in findings<br />

With respect to the findings <strong>of</strong> the sample information the null<br />

hypothesis is not rejected (the status quo is correct) in the following<br />

cases: The abnormal return in the pre event period is positive and<br />

the post <strong>merger</strong> performance is negative. This paper finds that the<br />

abnormal return during the event period is insignificant, the means<br />

by which an acquisition is acquired is irrelevant and hostile <strong>of</strong>fers<br />

and related <strong>of</strong>fers are associated with lower combined bidder-target<br />

stock returns. Furthermore, there is no statistical significance found<br />

in the comparison <strong>of</strong> equity and share post-<strong>merger</strong> performance.<br />

Generally speaking there seems to be little consistency in findings in<br />

the respective literature. For example Bhagat et al. (2004) find that<br />

friendly <strong>of</strong>fers, equity <strong>of</strong>fers, and diversifying <strong>of</strong>fers are associated<br />

with lower combined bidder-target stock returns. It is <strong>of</strong> interest to<br />

examine why this study comes up with results other than previous<br />

papers. Given that the samples <strong>of</strong> this study are European firms,<br />

even applying the same methodology as in this paper, the results<br />

must present systematic deviations to the mostly US-based studies.<br />

Therefore, there must be sample specific observations in average<br />

returns. For example the <strong>of</strong>ten stated Mandelker (1974) paper<br />

analyses 241 <strong>merger</strong>s that took place during 1941- 1962. Both the<br />

acquiring and the acquired firms were listed on the New York Stock<br />

Exchange (NYSE). In reviewing methodologies <strong>of</strong> authors who<br />

conclude that market efficiency is violated and pr<strong>of</strong>itable trading<br />

84


ules are found, Fama (1997) responds that the applied models are<br />

extremely important and a change in models <strong>of</strong>ten causes an<br />

anomaly to disappear. Fama (1997) states: “I argue that when this<br />

happens, the anomaly is not much evidence against market<br />

efficiency.” Fama (1997) emphasizes that market efficiency must be<br />

tested jointly with a model for expected (normal) returns. He<br />

stresses that tests <strong>of</strong> efficiency are always contaminated by a badmodel<br />

problem. Consequently, the problem grows with the return<br />

horizon: a bad-model that produces a spurious abnormal average<br />

return <strong>of</strong> x% per month eventually becomes statistically reliable,<br />

depending on what it is tested for, cumulative monthly abnormal<br />

returns (CARs) or mean abnormal returns. According to Fama<br />

(1997): “Bad-model problems are most acute with long-term buyand-hold<br />

abnormal returns (BHARs), which compound (multiply) an<br />

expected-return model’s problems in explaining short-term<br />

returns.” The BHAR approach as applied by Langetieg (1978) in the<br />

<strong>analysis</strong> section estimating abnormal returns as the difference<br />

between an event firm’s return on a non-event firm or portfolio that<br />

is similar in characteristics known to be related to average returns.<br />

Decreasing homogeny in sample characteristics challenges the<br />

BHAR approach. Some authors in the above <strong>analysis</strong> work with a<br />

less rigorous sample in terms <strong>of</strong> firm size. If this is combined with<br />

models such as the CAPM <strong>of</strong> Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965)<br />

where these models are said not to describe expected returns on<br />

small stocks sufficiently (Banz, 1981), the chance <strong>of</strong> less valid<br />

abnormal returns rises. Another source <strong>of</strong> different results in event<br />

studies is the investigated length <strong>of</strong> abnormal return measurement.<br />

An example is the Bradley et al. (1988) paper. They investigated<br />

takeovers during the period 1962-1984 and find contradictory to<br />

this study, positive and stable post-<strong>merger</strong> abnormal performance<br />

(7.4% <strong>of</strong> combined market value). However, they apply a postevent<br />

window <strong>of</strong> five days after the public announcement <strong>of</strong> the bid<br />

85


only. It can be argued that this is not sufficient in order to detect<br />

post-<strong>merger</strong> abnormal performance as it provides only a fraction <strong>of</strong><br />

the market’s assessment. Furthermore, equal-weight returns<br />

produce different results <strong>from</strong> value-weight returns. This paper<br />

works with an equal-weight approach whereas the Moeller et al.<br />

(2005) study works with value-weight returns. The impact on<br />

results is that abnormal returns shrink a lot and typically become<br />

statistically unreliable. Especially, the effect <strong>of</strong> event studies on<br />

small stocks is limited in this approach. Fama (1997) stresses:<br />

“small stocks are just a sure source <strong>of</strong> bad-model problems. Small<br />

stocks always pose problems in tests <strong>of</strong> asset pricing models, so<br />

they are prime candidates for bad-model problems in tests <strong>of</strong><br />

market efficiency on long-term returns.”<br />

In addition, Bhagat et al. (2004) define industry codes using<br />

Compustat SIC’s data, whereas Moeller et al. (2003a), as well as<br />

this paper, use SDC codes.<br />

Reasons <strong>of</strong> Failure <strong>of</strong> Merger Activity<br />

Most empirical studies <strong>from</strong> the literature review either based on<br />

shareholder wealth or accounting as well as the currency survey<br />

based on latter have failed to find positive relationship between<br />

<strong>merger</strong> activity and financial performance. There are a number <strong>of</strong><br />

arguments <strong>of</strong>fered in this regard.<br />

It is <strong>of</strong>ten claimed that the lack <strong>of</strong> market data biases studies <strong>of</strong><br />

accounting data. Indeed, it is argued that may be the post-<strong>merger</strong><br />

time period is insufficient long to capture the gains. Many<br />

performance gains may take time to either be achieved or be<br />

reflected to financial reports (Barnes (2000), Stickney & Brown<br />

(1999)).<br />

86


Another reason that justifies the absence <strong>of</strong> observed gains in the<br />

empirical evidence focuses on managerial behaviour. It is argued<br />

that there is a significant lack <strong>of</strong> alignment between the interests <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>shareholders</strong> and managers (Jenses 1986). Regarding this point <strong>of</strong><br />

view, <strong>merger</strong> activity is in the best interests <strong>of</strong> managers but not<br />

necessarily <strong>of</strong> <strong>shareholders</strong>. Managers are engaged in the takeover<br />

activity to increase their power and remuneration that are both<br />

assumed to be related to the institutional scale. This behaviour,<br />

however, comes at the expense <strong>of</strong> <strong>shareholders</strong> <strong>of</strong> the acquiring<br />

institution who in general overpay for such acquisitions and suffer<br />

dilution due to absence <strong>of</strong> mutual objectives with their agents.<br />

Buono et al (1985) and Spiegel & Gart (1996) attributed “Human<br />

resource problems” as being responsible for the major proposition<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> failure. Those studies have also examined the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>merger</strong>s on a wide range <strong>of</strong> management issues, such as culture<br />

and argue that the whole human resource problem could be<br />

reflected to the failure <strong>of</strong> cultural compatibility. Generally, the<br />

difference <strong>of</strong> culture between two counter parties might be derived<br />

<strong>from</strong> historical, geographical background, industrial nature and the<br />

attitude <strong>of</strong> executive managers. The failure <strong>of</strong> the integration <strong>of</strong><br />

culture might result in the employee work inefficiency and then in<br />

the decrease <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong> synergy.<br />

Clarck (1991) argues that <strong>of</strong>ten the <strong>merger</strong> deal is a threshold<br />

event for the best customers <strong>of</strong> the acquired company. If the<br />

acquired company was an important supplier in the past, the<br />

customers wonder whether the change forces it to make changes in<br />

vendor arrangements. Furthermore, the change in ownership has<br />

opened the door for competitors to approach the acquired best<br />

customers. Clarck’s study revealed that it cost approximately five<br />

times more to acquire a new customer than it does to retain and<br />

87


service an existing one. Also, it is revealed that 91% <strong>of</strong> unhappy<br />

customers will communicate their dissatisfaction to at least nine<br />

other people, which implies that the bad news will spread extremely<br />

quickly. Hence it is <strong>of</strong> significant importance to retain customers<br />

and new classifications caused by <strong>merger</strong> process may fail to<br />

achieve this.<br />

Eccles (1999) states that, many failures occur simply because the<br />

acquiring firm paid too much for the acquisition. In specific he<br />

claims, “if it wasn’t a good deal on the day it was made, it will never<br />

be “. Sudarsanam (1995) suggests that even experienced acquires<br />

who should know pricing acquisition better, sometimes get too<br />

attached to a deal. When that happens it is essential to have<br />

organisational disciplines in place that will rein in the emotion. The<br />

question for the two authors is not whether an acquirer has paid too<br />

high a price in an absolute sense rather he has paid more than the<br />

acquisition was worth to that particular company. What one<br />

company can afford will differ <strong>from</strong> what another company can<br />

afford and, more than likely, <strong>from</strong> the asking price. They conclude<br />

that the key to success in buying another company is, knowing the<br />

maximum price you can pay and then having the discipline not to<br />

pay a penny more.<br />

An additional reason, which can explain the cause <strong>of</strong> failure <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>merger</strong> activity in this specific survey, is antitrust regulations. In<br />

the U.K., <strong>merger</strong>s have been subject <strong>of</strong> antitrust regulation since<br />

1965, during which period the U.K. government’s policy has gone<br />

through distinct phases. While the main trust <strong>of</strong> antitrust regulation<br />

has been the maintenance <strong>of</strong> effective competition, many other<br />

issues <strong>of</strong> public interest have been considered, <strong>from</strong> time to time,<br />

relevant in determining whether a <strong>merger</strong> should be allowed. To<br />

88


conclude, it is not difficult to find that those regulations 1<br />

emphasised on passive encouragement rather than positive<br />

advocate for those companies that wanted to be engaged into a<br />

takeover process.<br />

Majority <strong>of</strong> the <strong>merger</strong> activity has to be permitted or examined by<br />

related authorities, a process that potentially postpones the<br />

proceeding <strong>of</strong> <strong>merger</strong>. Indeed to maintain competition the<br />

restriction in the remittance amount is confined, which might<br />

decrease the investment aspiration and opportunity. The role <strong>of</strong><br />

government in the U.K. appears to be more <strong>of</strong> an investigator<br />

rather than an assistant to <strong>merger</strong> process and this may be an<br />

explanation to the weak post <strong>merger</strong> performance.<br />

1 U.K. <strong>merger</strong> regime in accordance with Hughes (1993)<br />

89


Chapter 6: Conclusions<br />

Foreword<br />

The vast majority <strong>of</strong> previous studies have been conducted on the<br />

US market. The aim <strong>of</strong> this study was to determine if acquisition<br />

announcements have a similar impact on shares prices <strong>of</strong> European<br />

companies. Applying a rigorous approach by excluding all deals<br />

which do not fulfil the criteria discussed in the methodology, this<br />

study measured abnormal performance with the market model.<br />

Supported and rejected hypothesis’<br />

Earlier studies <strong>of</strong> completed acquisitions report that stockholders <strong>of</strong><br />

the firms involved earn abnormal returns before the effective date<br />

<strong>of</strong> acquisition (Dodd and Ruback, 1978). This pattern is found in this<br />

study, too. In fact, <strong>shareholders</strong> <strong>of</strong> bidding firms earn positive<br />

average abnormal returns, 250 trading-days before the event<br />

period. These gains are <strong>of</strong> substantial character. All things being<br />

equal, this leads to free cash flow in excess <strong>of</strong> that required to fund<br />

all positive NPV projects.<br />

If this excess cash flow is invested wisely in <strong>merger</strong> activities is<br />

evaluated in the event window and post-event window. However, it<br />

is found that pre acquisition performance is not an indicator for post<br />

acquisition performance. The author finds that firms announcing<br />

major acquisitions in 1999 and 2000 are characterised by negative<br />

performance during the post-event period. After 2001 these losses<br />

cannot be recovered. Therefore, acquisitions are costly for bidding<br />

firms during the investigated period. The losses can be attributed to<br />

few substantial negative acquisition announcements during the<br />

1999-2000 periods. It is expected that future results, excluding<br />

extreme periods like 1999 and 2000 reveals a more positive picture.<br />

90


It is concluded that the Jensen and Ruback (1992) findings <strong>of</strong><br />

negative post-<strong>merger</strong> performances are supported and that the<br />

efficient-market anomaly is not resolved. The underperformance<br />

holds for all years <strong>from</strong> 1997-2004 with the exception <strong>of</strong> 2001(AR<br />

0) and 2003 (AR 0.09). This paper also finds that hostile <strong>of</strong>fers and<br />

related <strong>of</strong>fers are associated with lower combined firm returns. An<br />

investigation <strong>of</strong> transaction characteristics shows that abnormal<br />

returns and the related-unrelated portfolio are significantly<br />

positively correlated.<br />

Reviewing the method <strong>of</strong> payment findings suggests that the<br />

medium with which an acquisition is financed is irrelevant. This<br />

challenges the proposition that deals made with shares signal<br />

payout <strong>of</strong> resources as a positive signal to investors. It also rejects<br />

the hypothesis that stock acquisitions tend to be more likely to be<br />

associated with growth opportunities and a shortage <strong>of</strong> free cash<br />

flow. Breaking the results down further into deal characteristics<br />

reveals the surprising result that diversification acquisitions<br />

outperform industry related deals. This is not only contradictory to<br />

the bulk <strong>of</strong> previous performance studies but also contradictory to<br />

agency theory. Jensen (1986) stresses that diversification<br />

programmes are more likely to generate losses than takeovers in<br />

the same line <strong>of</strong> business. He describes that managers with excess<br />

cash flows and unused borrowing power are more prone to poor<br />

investment decisions. However, he fails to explain why those factors<br />

are more severe for related than unrelated acquisitions. In addition,<br />

it was attempted to evaluate which characteristic can be used to<br />

predict abnormal returns. Therefore, the author modified the<br />

Fama/French three factor model. Cash to shares, hostile to friendly<br />

and related to unrelated portfolios are the identified independent<br />

variables which typically affect abnormal returns. The investigation<br />

reveals some directional results, but only the related-unrelated<br />

regression reveals statistical significance in t-statistics.<br />

91


The management factor<br />

One plus one makes three: this equation is the special alchemy <strong>of</strong><br />

an acquisition. Given the weak post <strong>merger</strong> performance, it can be<br />

concluded that the the price <strong>of</strong> making a mistake is greater than the<br />

price <strong>of</strong> missing an opportunity. Reasons for underperformance<br />

vary: there may be a vast difference between the price one<br />

company can pay for an acquisition and the price another can pay.<br />

The key to success in buying another company is knowing the<br />

maximum price to pay and having the discipline not to pay more.<br />

Paying too much because <strong>of</strong> ‘strategic reasons’ can be attributed to<br />

‘individual decision making’ (Roll, 1986). The poor post-<strong>merger</strong><br />

performance can be referred to managerial opportunism and glory<br />

seeking. The executive ego, which is boosted by buying the<br />

competition, is a major force in M&A, especially when combined<br />

with the influences <strong>from</strong> bankers, lawyers and other assorted<br />

advisers who can earn big fees <strong>from</strong> clients engaged in acquisitions.<br />

Many studies over the last several decades have found that people<br />

are generally overconfident about the accuracy <strong>of</strong> their knowledge.<br />

In an M&A environment, an overconfident CEO is prone to pursue<br />

risky deals, or pay too much, because she overestimates the return<br />

she can produce <strong>from</strong> an acquisition. Shefrin (2004, in Teach, 2004)<br />

argues: “Every CEO who goes into [an acquisition] thinks he is<br />

different – that he will be able to pull it <strong>of</strong>f.” Another reason why<br />

managers engage in acquisition activities beyond the optimal size <strong>of</strong><br />

their firm is management compensation. Murphy (1985) finds that<br />

management compensation is positively related to the size <strong>of</strong> the<br />

firm.<br />

92


Unresolved problems and suggestions for further research<br />

The existing literature on the post-acquisition performance <strong>of</strong><br />

bidding firms is divided. Given the conflicting results to prior<br />

studies, it cannot be concluded that issues <strong>of</strong> over and<br />

underperformance are solved. The findings are contradictory to a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> studies, which is due to several reasons. Two possibilities<br />

seem to be left as to why underperformance is found in event<br />

studies in finance. Either the abnormal returns are due to mispricing,<br />

or the applied methodologies are incorrect. Today, the<br />

reason for the significant underperformance post-<strong>merger</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

remains unknown. In addition, the unsolved contradiction to the<br />

efficient market hypothesis is why share prices adjust to corporate<br />

signals with some time delay, slowly over a period <strong>of</strong> months or<br />

years. Given that acquisitions are one way managers spend cash<br />

instead <strong>of</strong> paying it out to <strong>shareholders</strong>, the challenge to overcome<br />

is how to solve paying out the excess cash but not investing it in<br />

negative NPV acquisitions.<br />

So far, little is known about European acquisitions as the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

researchers have focused on the US market. Given the importance<br />

<strong>of</strong> this market, this is surprising. The author hopes that this work<br />

contributes to the knowledge in acquisition performance studies.<br />

European specific characteristics such as the bulk <strong>of</strong> non-stock listed<br />

businesses cannot be excluded on a continuing basis. The author<br />

suggests that stock market listed versus non-stock market listed<br />

deals should be analysed. This is left for further research.<br />

93


References<br />

Agrawal, A., Jaffe, J.F. and Mandelker, G.N. (1992). ‘The <strong>Post</strong>-<br />

Merger Performance <strong>of</strong> Acquiring Firms: A Re-examination <strong>of</strong> an<br />

Anomaly’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 47(4), pp. 1605–21.<br />

Amihud, Y., B. Lev, and N. Travlos, (1990). ‘Corporate Control and<br />

the Choice <strong>of</strong> Investment Financing: The Case <strong>of</strong> Corporate<br />

Acquisitions’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 45 (2), pp.603-616.<br />

Asquith, P. (1983). ‘Merger Bids, Uncertainty, and Stockholder<br />

Returns’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol. 11(1-4), pp.51-83.<br />

Asquith, P., Bruner, R. and Mullins, D. (1987). ‘Mergers Returns and<br />

The Form Of Financing’. Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the Seminar on the Analysis<br />

<strong>of</strong> Security Prices 34, pp.115-146.<br />

Berenson, M. Levine, D.M. Krehbiel, T.C. (2004). Basic Business<br />

Statistics. Prentice Hall; 9th Bk&Cdr edition. pp. 247-266.<br />

Berkovitch, E. and M. P. Narayanan. (1993). ‘Motives for Takeovers:<br />

An Empirical Investigation’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial and Quantitative<br />

Analysis. Vol. 28 (3), pp. 347-364.<br />

Bradley, M., Desai, A. and Kim, E. H. (1983). ‘The Rationale Behind<br />

Interfirm Tender Offers: Information or Synergy’ Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Financial Economics. Vol.11 (1-4), pp. 183-206.<br />

Brealey, R.A., and Myers, S.C. (2003). Principles <strong>of</strong> Corporate<br />

Finance. USA: Tata McGraw-Hill.<br />

94


Brown, S.J., and Warner, J.B. (1985). ‘Using Daily Stock Returns:<br />

The Case <strong>of</strong> Event Studies’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol. 14,<br />

pp. 3–31.<br />

Buch, C.M, and DeLong, G. (2004). ‘Cross-border Bank Mergers:<br />

What Lures the Rare Animal’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Banking and Finance. Vol.<br />

28 (9), pp.2077-2102.<br />

Carhart, M.M., 1997. On persistence in mutual fund performance.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance 52. pp. 57-82.<br />

Chan, L., Hamao, Y. and Lakonishok, J. (1991). ‘Fundamentals and<br />

Stock Returns in Japan’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol.46 (5), pp. 1739-<br />

1765.<br />

Chung, K. S., and. Weston, J. F. (1982), ‘Diversification and<br />

Mergers in a Strategic Longrange-planning Framework’, in Keenan,<br />

M. and White, L. J. (ed.), Mergers and Acquisitions: Current<br />

problems in Perspective, Lexington, MA: D.C.Heath<br />

Comment, R. and Schwert, G. W. (1995). ‘Poison or Placebo<br />

<strong>Evidence</strong> on the Deterrence and Wealth Effects <strong>of</strong> Modern<br />

Antitakeover Measures.’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol. 39(1),<br />

pp. 3-43.<br />

Damodaran, A. Chapter <strong>from</strong> the forthcoming corporate finance<br />

book “Acquisitions and Takeovers” [online]. 2005. Available <strong>from</strong>:<br />

http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/ [Accessed 02 June 2005].<br />

DeBondt, W. F. M., and R. H. Thaler. (1985). ‘Does the Stock<br />

Market Overreact’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 40(3), pp.793-805.<br />

95


and ------.(1987). ‘Further <strong>Evidence</strong> <strong>of</strong> Investor Overreaction and<br />

Stock Market Seasonality’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 42 (3), pp.557-<br />

582.<br />

Boehmer, E. (1987). ‘Busienss groups, bank control, and large<br />

<strong>shareholders</strong>: An <strong>analysis</strong> <strong>of</strong> German takeovers’, Working paper,<br />

July 1998: Available <strong>from</strong><br />

http://www.ecgi.org/conferences/economic_performance/document<br />

s/mvalue3.pdf. [Accessed 14 July 2005].<br />

Brav, A., (2000), Inference in long-horizon event studies: A<br />

Bayesian approach with application to initial public <strong>of</strong>ferings, Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Finance 55. pp. 1979-2016.<br />

Dodd, P. and Ruback, R., (1977). ‘Tender Offers and Shareholder<br />

Returns: An Empirical Analysis.’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol.<br />

5 (3), pp.351-373.<br />

Dreman, D. and Berry M. (1995), ‘Overreaction, Underreaction, and<br />

the Low-P/E Effect’. The Financial Analysts Journal. Vol. 51(4), pp.<br />

21-30.<br />

Eccles, R., Lanes, K. and Wilson T. Are You Paying Too Much for<br />

That Acquisition [online]. Harvard Business Review, 1999.<br />

Available<br />

<strong>from</strong>:<br />

http://harvardbusinessonline.hbsp.harvard.edu/b02/en/common/ite<br />

m_detail.jhtmlreferral=9420&id=99402[Accessed 12 July 2005].<br />

Eckbo, B.E. and Langohr, H. (1989). ‘Information Disclosure,<br />

Methods <strong>of</strong> Payment and Takeover Premiums: Public and Private<br />

Tender Offers in France’, Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol. 24<br />

(2), pp. 363–403.<br />

96


eurostat.cec.eu.int. Available <strong>from</strong>:<br />

http://epp.eurostat.cec.eu.int/portal/page_pageid=1996,4532373<br />

4&_dad=portal&_schema=PORTAL&screen. [Accessed 10 July<br />

2005].<br />

Fama, E. F. (1965). ‘The Behaviour <strong>of</strong> Stock Market Prices.’ Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Business. Vol.38 (1), pp. 34-105.<br />

Fama, E. F. (1970). ‘Efficient Capital Markets: a Review <strong>of</strong> Theory<br />

and Empirical Work’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 25 (2), pp.383-417.<br />

Fama, E. F. and French, K. (1993). ‘Common Risk Factors in the<br />

Returns on Stock and Bonds.’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol.<br />

33(1), pp. 3-56.<br />

Fama, E. F., Fisher, L., Jensen, M. C. and Roll, R. W. (1969). ‘The<br />

Adjustment <strong>of</strong> Stock Prices to New Information.’ International<br />

Economic Review. Vol. 10 (1), pp.1-21.<br />

Fama, E. F., (1976). Foundations <strong>of</strong> Finance. New York: Basic<br />

Books.<br />

Fama, E. F., (1996). ‘Multifactor Portfolio Efficiency and Multifactor<br />

Asset Pricing’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial and Quantitative Analysis. Vol. 31<br />

(4), pp.441-465.<br />

Finkelstein, S. Cross-Border Mergers and Acquisitions [online].<br />

1999. Available<br />

at:http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/syd.finkelstein/arti<br />

cles/CrossBorder.pdf[Accessed 05 July 2005].<br />

97


Firth, M. (1980). ‘Takeovers, Shareholder Returns, and the Theory<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Firm’. Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics. Vol.94 (2), pp.235-<br />

260.<br />

Focarelli, D. and Pozzolo, A., (2001). ‘The Patterns <strong>of</strong> Cross-Border<br />

Bank Mergers and Shareholdings in OECD Countries’. Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Banking and Finance. Vol. 25 (12), pp. 2305-2337.<br />

Franks, J., Harris, R. and Mayer, C. (1988). Means <strong>of</strong> Payment in<br />

Takeovers: Results for the United Kingdom and the United States.<br />

In: Alan J. Auerbach, ed. Corporate Takeovers: Causes and<br />

Consequences, Chicago: University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Press.<br />

Franks, J., Harris, R. and Titman, S. (1991). ‘The <strong>Post</strong><strong>merger</strong><br />

Share-Price Performance <strong>of</strong> Acquiring Firms’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial<br />

Economics. Vol. 29(1), pp. 81-96.<br />

Funds Management Research Centre (2002) Survivorship bias<br />

study. Available <strong>from</strong><br />

http://www.fundx.com/jul73/researchtable2.cfm. [Accessed 02<br />

August 2005.]<br />

Golbe, D., and White, L. (1987). A Time Series Analysis <strong>of</strong> Mergers<br />

and Acquisitions in the U.S. Economy. In: A. Auerbach, ed.,<br />

Corporate Takeovers. Chicago: University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Press, pp.<br />

265-305.<br />

Gugler, K., Mueller, D.C., and Yurtoglu, B.The Determinants <strong>of</strong><br />

Merger Waves [online]. 2005. Available at:<br />

http://www.uu.nl/content/05-15.pdf [Accessed 25 July 2005].<br />

98


Han, K., Suk, D. and Sung H. (1998). ‘The <strong>Evidence</strong> <strong>of</strong> Bidders'<br />

Overpayment in Takeovers: The Valuation Ratios Approach.’ The<br />

Financial Review. Vol.33 (2), pp.55-68.<br />

Investorwords. Definition <strong>of</strong> premiums, Available <strong>from</strong><br />

http://www.investorwords.com/3785/premium.html. [Accessed<br />

28.06.2005]<br />

Jackson, R., and Gart, A. (1999). ‘Determinants and nondeterminants<br />

<strong>of</strong> bank <strong>merger</strong> premiums’. The Mid-Atlantic Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Business. Vol. 35(4), pp.149-158.<br />

Jarrell, G.A., Brickley, J.A. and J.M. Netter. (1988). ‘The Market for<br />

Corporate Control: The <strong>Evidence</strong> since 1980.’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic<br />

Perspectives. Vol. 2 (1), pp.49–68.<br />

Jarrell, G. A. and Poulsen, A. B. (1989). ‘Stock trading before the<br />

announcement <strong>of</strong> tender <strong>of</strong>fers: Insider trading or market<br />

anticipation’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Law, Economics, and Organization. Vol. 5,<br />

pp. 225– 248.<br />

Jennings, R.H. and Mazzeo, M.A. (1993). ‘Competing bids, target<br />

management resistance, and the structure <strong>of</strong> takeover bids.’ Review<br />

<strong>of</strong> Financial Studies. Vol. 6(4), pp.883-909.<br />

Jensen, M. and Ruback, R.S. (1983). ‘The market for corporate<br />

control: The scientific evidence,’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol.<br />

11(1-4), pp.5-50.<br />

Jensen, Michael C., (1986) "Agency Cost Of Free Cash Flow,<br />

Corporate Finance, and Takeovers" . American Economic Review,<br />

Vol. 76, No. 2, May 1986<br />

99


Jarrell, G., Brickley, J.A. and Netter, J.M., “The Market for Corporate<br />

Control: The Empirical <strong>Evidence</strong> Since 1980,” Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic<br />

Perspectives 2, 1988, pp. 49-68.<br />

Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A. (1979). ‘Prospect Theory: An<br />

Analysis <strong>of</strong> Decisions Under Risk.’ Econometrica. Vol.47 (2), pp.<br />

263-291.<br />

Murphy, K.J. (1985). Corporate Performance and Managerial<br />

Remuneration: An Empirical Analysis, Journal <strong>of</strong> Accounting &<br />

Economics, 7. pp. 11-41.<br />

Kothari, S.P. and Warner, J. B. (1997). ‘Measuring Long-Horizon<br />

Security Price Performance’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, Vol. 43<br />

(3), pp. 301-340.<br />

Kothari, S. P. and Warner, J. B. (2004). ‘Econometrics <strong>of</strong> event<br />

studies’. Working Paper, Tuck School <strong>of</strong> Business at Dartmouth.<br />

Lintner, J. (1965). ‘The Valuation <strong>of</strong> Risk Assets and Selection <strong>of</strong><br />

Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets’. Review<br />

<strong>of</strong> Economics and Statistics. Vol.47(1), pp.13-37.<br />

Malkiel, B.G. (2003). ‘The Efficient Market Hypothesis and Its<br />

Critics’. Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 91.<br />

Markham, J. “Survey <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Evidence</strong> and Findings on Mergers.” In<br />

Business Concentration and Price Policy, Princeton (1955):<br />

Princeton University Press.<br />

Meulbroek, L. K., and Hart, C. (1997). ‘The Effect <strong>of</strong> Illegal Insider<br />

Trading on Takeover Premia.’ European Finance Review. Volume<br />

1(1), pp.51-80.<br />

100


Miller, M. (1977). ‘Debt and Taxes’, Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, Vol. 32(2),<br />

pp.261-275.<br />

Mitchell, M. and Stafford, E. (2000). ‘Managerial Decisions and<br />

Long-Term Stock-Price Performance’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Business. Vol.73<br />

(3), pp.287-330.<br />

Modigliani F., and Miller M. (1958). ‘The Cost <strong>of</strong> Capital, Corporation<br />

Finance and the Theory <strong>of</strong> Investment.’ American Economic Review.<br />

Vol. 48(3), pp. 261-297.<br />

Moeller, S., Schlingemann, F. and Stulz, R. (2005). ‘Wealth<br />

Destruction on a Massive Scale A Study <strong>of</strong> Scquiring Firm Returns<br />

in The Recent Merger Wave.’ The Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 60 (2),<br />

pp.757-782.<br />

Morck, R., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., (1990). ‘The Stock Market And<br />

Investment: Is The Market A Sideshow’ Brookings Papers on<br />

Economic Activity. 1990 (2), pp.157-215.<br />

Morck, R., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., (1990b). ‘Do Managerial<br />

Objectives Drive Bad Acquisitions’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 45(1),<br />

pp. 31-48.<br />

Myers, S., and Majluf, N. (1984). ‘Corporate Financing and<br />

Investment Decisions when Firms have Information that Investors<br />

do not have.’ Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol. 13, pp.187-221.<br />

Nail, L.A., Megginson W.L and Maquieira, C. (1998). ‘Wealth<br />

Creation versus Wealth Redistributions in Pure Stock-for-Stock<br />

Mergers’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol. 48 (1), pp.3-33.<br />

101


Nelson, R. Merger Movements in American Industry 1895-1956,<br />

Princeton (1959): Princeton University Press.<br />

Philippatos, G.C. and Baird, P.L. III. (1996). ‘<strong>Post</strong><strong>merger</strong><br />

Performance, Managerial Superiority and The Market For Corporate<br />

Control.’ Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 17(1), pp. 45-55.<br />

Rhodes-Kropf, M. and Viswanathan, S. (2004). ‘Market Valuation<br />

and Merger Waves’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 59(6), pp. 2685-2718.<br />

Roll, R. (1986). ‘The Hubris Hypothesis <strong>of</strong> Corporate Takeovers’.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Business. Vol. 59 (2), pp. 197-216.<br />

Ross, S. A., “The Arbitrage Theory <strong>of</strong> Capital Asset Pricing”, Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Economic Theory, (1976), 13, p.341–360.<br />

Schwert, W. (1996). ‘Mark-Up Pricing in Mergers and Acquisitions,’<br />

NBER Working Papers 4863, National Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economic Research,<br />

Inc.<br />

Servaes, H. (1991). ‘Tobin’s Q and the Gains <strong>from</strong> Takeovers’.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol. 66(1), pp. 409-419.<br />

Sharpe, W. F. (1964). ‘Capital Asset Prices: A Theory <strong>of</strong> Market<br />

Equilibrium Under Conditions <strong>of</strong> Risk’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol.19<br />

(3), pp.425-442.<br />

Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational Exuberance. Princeton: Princeton<br />

University Press<br />

Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (2003). ‘Stock Market Driven<br />

Acquisitions’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics. Vol.70(3), pp.295-<br />

311.<br />

102


Shughart, W. F. and Tollison, R. D., (1984). ‘The Use <strong>of</strong> Inputs by<br />

the Federal Reserve System: Reply.’ American Economic Review.<br />

Vol. 74 (5), pp.1121-23.<br />

Sirower, M. L. (1997). The Synergy Trap: How Companies Lose the<br />

Acquisition Game. New York: The Free Press.<br />

Teach, E. (2004). Watch how you think: Insights <strong>from</strong> behavioural<br />

finance could change the way companies approach <strong>merger</strong>s and<br />

acquisitions. February 2004. Available <strong>from</strong><br />

http://www.cfoeurope.com/displayStory.cfm/2383092.<br />

12 June 2005].<br />

[Accessed<br />

Thaler, R.H. (2000). ‘From Homo Economicus to Homo Sapiens’.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic Perspectives. Vol. 14 (1), pp. 133-141.<br />

Travlos, N.G., (1987). ‘Corporate Takeovers Bids, Method <strong>of</strong><br />

Payment, and Bidding Firms' Stock Return’. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance. Vol.<br />

42(4), pp. 943-963.<br />

Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1981). ‘The Framing <strong>of</strong> Decisions<br />

and The Psychology Of Choice’. Science. Vol. 211, pp.453–458.<br />

Weston, J. (1953). The Role <strong>of</strong> Mergers in the Growth <strong>of</strong> Large<br />

Firms,<br />

Berkeley (1953): University <strong>of</strong> California Press. pp. 79-96.<br />

Weston, J.F., Chung K.S. and Siu J.A. (1998). Takeovers,<br />

Restructuring, And Corporate Governance (2 nd edition <strong>of</strong> Mergers,<br />

Acquisitions, And Corporate Control, 1990). Prentice Hall, Upper<br />

Saddle River, N.J. pp. 273-312.<br />

103


Appendices<br />

Appendix 1 abnormal performance<br />

Performance estimation period<br />

estimation period<br />

Acquiror Ri Rm<br />

Glaxo 1995 0.17 -0.03<br />

Scottish Power 1995 0.01 0.16<br />

Hanson 1995 -0.08 0.10<br />

Rentokil 1996 0.39 0.17<br />

Kvaerner 1996 -0.26 0.15<br />

Scottish Power 1996 0.05 0.13<br />

II<br />

Cable and Wir. 1996 0.11 0.12<br />

Rallye 1997 0.20 0.21<br />

Lafarge 1997 0.26 0.18<br />

Thyssen 1997 0.30 0.25<br />

DSM 1998 0.04 0.16<br />

CGE 1998 -0.45 0.21<br />

Akzo 1998 0.42 0.28<br />

Carrefour I 1998 0.07 0.26<br />

Total I 1998 0.15 0.19<br />

San<strong>of</strong>i 1998 0.46 0.20<br />

Astra 1998 0.29 0.17<br />

Danisco 1999 -0.22 0.19<br />

Gecina 1999 0.16 0.02<br />

Vivendi 1999 0.19 0.04<br />

Cap Gemini 1999 0.16 0.01<br />

Total II 1999 0.08 0.01<br />

Linde 1999 0.39 0.10<br />

Carrefour II 1999 -0.47 0.11<br />

Vedior 1999 0.65 0.13<br />

Finmeccanica 1999 -0.16 0.20<br />

RWE 1999 -0.04 0.16<br />

104


Anglo American 1999 0.66 0.13<br />

Vodafone 1999 -0.18 0.15<br />

Glaxo II 2000 -0.08 0.20<br />

Clariant 2000 0.46 0.24<br />

Saint Gobain 2000 0.15 0.24<br />

BP 2000 0.75 0.22<br />

Telefonica 2000 -0.28 0.16<br />

ENI 2000 0.84 0.15<br />

France Telecom 2000 0.82 0.10<br />

Publics<br />

2000 0.32 0.19<br />

Grouppe<br />

Vivendi II 2000 -0.03 0.12<br />

Vinci 2000 0.10 0.09<br />

Novartis 2000 -0.14 0.08<br />

Ahold 2000 2.26 0.10<br />

Tiscali 2000 0.00 0.07<br />

Smiths 2000 -0.11 -0.17<br />

RWEII 2000 0.19 -0.16<br />

ENI II 2000 -0.25 -0.18<br />

Lafarge II 2001 -0.06 -0.24<br />

Schneider 2001 0.01 -0.06<br />

RWE III 2002 -0.19 -0.11<br />

National Grid 2002 0.22 -0.16<br />

Kone 2002 0.14 0.25<br />

ENI III 2002 0.16 -0.10<br />

Morisson 2003 0.53 -0.19<br />

Roche 2003 0.28 0.29<br />

Svendborg 2003 0.25 0.08<br />

San<strong>of</strong>i II 2004 0.19 0.13<br />

UCB 2004 0.47 0.33<br />

COUNT 56 56<br />

MEAN 0.19 0.10<br />

MEDIAN 0.15 0.13<br />

MAX 2.26 0.33<br />

MIN -0.47 -0.24<br />

Per cent winners 69.64 82.14<br />

Per cent losers 30.36 17.86<br />

105


Performance event period<br />

event period<br />

Acquiror<br />

AR<br />

Glaxo 1995 -0.07<br />

Scottish Power 1995 -0.08<br />

Hanson 1995 0.01<br />

Rentokil 1996 -0.04<br />

Kvaerner 1996 0.07<br />

Scottish Power II 1996 -0.09<br />

Cable and Wir. 1996 0.05<br />

Rallye 1997 -0.08<br />

Lafarge 1997 0.00<br />

Thyssen 1997 -0.02<br />

DSM 1998 0.07<br />

CGE 1998 0.11<br />

Akzo 1998 -0.05<br />

Carrefour I 1998 -0.18<br />

Total I 1998 -0.09<br />

San<strong>of</strong>i 1998 0.06<br />

Astra 1998 0.15<br />

Danisco 1999 0.01<br />

Gecina 1999 -0.07<br />

Vivendi 1999 0.07<br />

Cap Gemini 1999 -0.05<br />

Total II 1999 -0.01<br />

Linde 1999 -0.11<br />

Carrefour II 1999 -0.35<br />

Vedior 1999 0.06<br />

Finmeccanica 1999 0.14<br />

RWE 1999 0.00<br />

Anglo American 1999 -0.09<br />

Vodafone 1999 -0.06<br />

Glaxo II 2000 0.05<br />

Clariant 2000 -0.04<br />

Saint Gobain 2000 -0.34<br />

BP 2000 0.10<br />

Telefonica 2000 -0.15<br />

106


ENI 2000 0.09<br />

France Telecom 2000 -0.12<br />

Publics Grouppe 2000 -0.02<br />

Vivendi II 2000 -0.17<br />

Vinci 2000 0.07<br />

Novartis 2000 -0.03<br />

Ahold 2000 0.01<br />

Tiscali 2000 -0.39<br />

Smiths 2000 -0.33<br />

RWEII 2000 -0.12<br />

ENI II 2000 0.03<br />

Lafarge II 2001 0.18<br />

Schneider 2001 0.10<br />

RWE III 2002 0.05<br />

National Grid 2002 0.15<br />

Kone 2002 -0.07<br />

ENI III 2002 0.05<br />

Morisson 2003 -0.12<br />

Roche 2003 -0.19<br />

Svendborg 2003 0.05<br />

San<strong>of</strong>i II 2004 -0.09<br />

UCB 2004 -0.06<br />

COUNT 56<br />

MEAN -0.03<br />

MEDIAN -0.03<br />

MAX 0.18<br />

MIN -0.39<br />

Per cent winners 0.43<br />

Per cent losers 0.57<br />

107


Performance post-event period<br />

post-event period<br />

Acquiror<br />

AR<br />

Glaxo 1995 -0.11<br />

Scottish Power 1995 -0.05<br />

Hanson 1995 -0.26<br />

Rentokil 1996 -0.10<br />

Kvaerner 1996 0.60<br />

Scottish Power II 1996 -0.05<br />

Cable and Wir. 1996 0.07<br />

Rallye 1997 -0.24<br />

Lafarge 1997 -0.02<br />

Thyssen 1997 -0.66<br />

DSM 1998 -0.04<br />

CGE 1998 0.50<br />

Akzo 1998 -0.69<br />

Carrefour I 1998 0.26<br />

Total I 1998 0.13<br />

San<strong>of</strong>i 1998 -0.34<br />

Astra 1998 -0.21<br />

Danisco 1999 -0.17<br />

Gecina 1999 -0.29<br />

Vivendi 1999 0.03<br />

Cap Gemini 1999 0.23<br />

Total II 1999 0.16<br />

Linde 1999 -0.35<br />

Carrefour II 1999 0.26<br />

Vedior 1999 0.41<br />

Finmeccanica 1999 0.43<br />

RWE 1999 0.17<br />

Anglo American 1999 -0.61<br />

Vodafone 1999 -0.65<br />

Glaxo II 2000 0.21<br />

Clariant 2000 -0.26<br />

Saint Gobain 2000 -1.04<br />

BP 2000 -0.49<br />

Telefonica 2000 -0.86<br />

108


ENI 2000 0.33<br />

France Telecom 2000 -1.30<br />

Publics Grouppe 2000 -0.76<br />

Vivendi II 2000 -0.47<br />

Vinci 2000 0.29<br />

Novartis 2000 -0.15<br />

Ahold 2000 0.05<br />

Tiscali 2000 -0.78<br />

Smiths 2000 0.01<br />

RWEII 2000 0.15<br />

ENI II 2000 -0.24<br />

Lafarge II 2001 0.26<br />

Schneider 2001 -0.26<br />

RWE III 2002 -0.53<br />

National Grid 2002 0.05<br />

Kone 2002 -0.17<br />

ENI III 2002 -0.01<br />

Morisson 2003 0.23<br />

Roche 2003 -0.30<br />

Svendborg 2003 0.16<br />

San<strong>of</strong>i II 2004 -0.12<br />

UCB 2004 -0.23<br />

COUNT 56<br />

MEAN -0.14<br />

MEDIAN -0.10<br />

MAX 0.60<br />

MIN -1.30<br />

Per cent winners 0.39<br />

Per cent losers 0.61<br />

109


Appendix 2 Regression <strong>of</strong> Characteristics (SPSS)<br />

Two-stage Least Squares<br />

110


Appendix 3 Performance Graph DS non-financial European stock<br />

index to two major European stock indeces.<br />

111

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!