16.03.2015 Views

Macroeconomics, KrugmanWells Chapter #16 Page 1 ... - Rasco.name

Macroeconomics, KrugmanWells Chapter #16 Page 1 ... - Rasco.name

Macroeconomics, KrugmanWells Chapter #16 Page 1 ... - Rasco.name

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Macroeconomics</strong>, Krugman­Wells<br />

<strong>Chapter</strong> <strong>#16</strong><br />

<strong>Page</strong> 1<br />

Question: Since inflation measures the cost of living,<br />

what is the value of measuring the core rate of inflation which excludes food and<br />

energy, goods that everyone must continue to buy?<br />

Paul Krugman: The whole issue of the core rate of inflation has actually been the<br />

subject of a pretty funny debate in the last, last couple of years.<br />

That’s because, actually, we've been in a situation where energy prices, in<br />

particular, have gone up a lot;<br />

the effects of hurricane Katrina and hurricane Rita have led to high gasoline<br />

prices, high natural gas prices;<br />

some food items also going up quite a lot in price. And so, you have this headline<br />

rate of inflation, as people say:<br />

the regular consumer price index going up pretty fast; at the same time, the core<br />

rate of inflation, excluding food and energy, going up much less fast.<br />

And when people said, “Well, okay, core inflation is still under control,” there’s<br />

been a lot of caustic remarks about how, well,<br />

there’s no inflation if you don't count the inflation. But there’s actually a reason,<br />

there’s a very good reason for focusing on core inflation.<br />

It goes back to some of the things we discuss in <strong>Chapter</strong> 16. When we think about<br />

how inflation works, we—in a moderate inflation,<br />

moderate­to­low­inflation economy like the United States, the really serious issue<br />

is not whether you have inflation for a few months or even for a year or two;<br />

it’s when inflation gets built into expectations and develops a kind of inertia—and<br />

then, this can be very, very hard to bring it back down.<br />

That’s the story of the 1980's: we had allowed inflation to get built into<br />

expectations;<br />

and then, there was an extremely painful process of squeezing the inflation out of<br />

the economy, which involved a period of very high unemployment.


<strong>Macroeconomics</strong>, Krugman­Wells<br />

<strong>Chapter</strong> <strong>#16</strong><br />

<strong>Page</strong> 2<br />

Most economists working in this area (certainly, the economists at the Federal<br />

Reserve) believe that the core rate of inflation,<br />

leaving out the food and energy prices, is a better measure of the part of inflation<br />

that's got inertia—the part that once it's gotten up is hard to get back down.<br />

The idea is that nobody thinks that the result, the inflation that results from the<br />

price of gasoline going from two dollars to three dollars temporarily,<br />

as the result of a hurricane—nobody is going to build that into their expectations.<br />

But a more sustained increase in prices that doesn't reflect food and energy,<br />

that reflects all kinds of things, is a much better measure of the kind of thing that<br />

once you got that up there, it's hard to get back down.<br />

So, if the inflation rate goes briefly from two to four percent because of food and<br />

energy—no problems.<br />

If the inflation rate goes from two to four percent because, even though food and<br />

energy prices have been going no place in particular,<br />

that’s much more of a source of worry because it may be quite difficult to get<br />

those extra two points of inflation back out of the system.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!