10.07.2015 Views

WTO negotiations on agriculture: problems and ways ahead - L20.org

WTO negotiations on agriculture: problems and ways ahead - L20.org

WTO negotiations on agriculture: problems and ways ahead - L20.org

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> Negotiati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> Agriculture:Problems <strong>and</strong> Ways Ahead“Background Briefing Paper for Sessi<strong>on</strong> 1”Kevin WatkinsIntroducti<strong>on</strong>‘We recognise the need for all peoples to benefit from the increased opportunities <strong>and</strong>welfare gains that the multilateral trading system generates.’Ministerial Declarati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>, 14 November 2001Three years <strong>on</strong>, the encouraging words adopted at the start of the Doha Round have ahollow ring. So far, the ‘development’ round has delivered little more thanencouraging rhetoric, punctuated by deadlock <strong>and</strong> episodic breakdown. Rich countrieshave not delivered the reforms needed to make the global trading system a morepowerful force for development. Failure to change this picture will inevitably damagethe legitimacy of the rules-based system represented by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>, with attendantimplicati<strong>on</strong>s for multilateralism. There is a broad c<strong>on</strong>sensus that the costs of failurewill be high. Can they be avoided?The answer to this questi<strong>on</strong> will depend crucially <strong>on</strong> progress in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong><strong>agriculture</strong>. Reform of the rules governing agricultural trade is essential for bothsubstantive <strong>and</strong> symbolic reas<strong>on</strong>s. The substantive reas<strong>on</strong>s are well known.Industrialised-country support programmes restrict access to Northern markets,generate large surpluses, <strong>and</strong> subsidise exports. Producers in developing countries – ac<strong>on</strong>stituency that includes a large proporti<strong>on</strong> of the world's poorest people – areexcluded from market opportunities <strong>and</strong> forced to compete against heavily subsidisedcompetiti<strong>on</strong> in internati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong> even in local markets.The symbolic relevance of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> relates to the legitimacy ofthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> system itself. Most developing countries see a change in the rules <strong>on</strong><strong>agriculture</strong> as a litmus test for the commitment of rich countries to a fairerinternati<strong>on</strong>al trading system. Noti<strong>on</strong>s of fairness may be disputed, but currentagricultural rules <strong>and</strong> trade practices enshrine what can <strong>on</strong>ly be described as a set ofdouble st<strong>and</strong>ards. Northern governments seldom miss an opportunity preach thevirtues of openness to developing countries, while remaining resolutely protecti<strong>on</strong>istthemselves. Rules in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> perpetuate a system under which the distributi<strong>on</strong> ofopportunity in agricultural trade is shaped not by comparative advantage, but bycomparative access to subsidies – an area in which rich countries have an unrivalledadvantage. Failure to change this picture will inevitably reinforce a percepti<strong>on</strong> that<str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules skew the benefits of trade <strong>and</strong> globalisati<strong>on</strong> towards the industrialisedworld.In an optimistic scenario, the Doha Round could still produce real change. In past<str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rounds, agricultural trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> were essentially a bilateral EU–USaffair. Developing countries – the vast majority of <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> members, with the biggeststake in agricultural trade rules – were byst<strong>and</strong>ers. Negotiating outcomes reflected1


inequalities in negotiating power. Thus the Uruguay Round Agreement <strong>on</strong> Agriculture(AoA) provided a multilateral façade for what was a bilateral arrangement designed toaccommodate, rather than c<strong>on</strong>strain, EU <strong>and</strong> US subsidies. The arrival of the G20 <strong>and</strong>the increased voice of African governments during the Cancun ministerial summithave fundamentally shifted the terms of engagement <strong>on</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, making a repeatperformance of the Uruguay Round unlikely.Prospects for a positive outcome have been strengthened by wider developments.Dispute-panel rulings have directly challenged EU <strong>and</strong> US agricultural supportsystems, creating precedents for future acti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong>, by extensi<strong>on</strong>, incentives fornorthern governments to seek a rules-based resoluti<strong>on</strong>. With the expiry of the PeaceClause, Northern governments must now weigh c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> legality in thebalance of domestic reform c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s.Since Cancun, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> negotiating atmosphere has been characterised by rapidmood swings. The most recent swing appears favourable to a settlement, with the EU<strong>and</strong> the US adopting more c<strong>on</strong>ciliatory language. Having threatened a new wave ofunilateralism <strong>and</strong> bilateralism, the US Trade Representative, Robert Zoellick, hasrecently indicated a str<strong>on</strong>g preference for multilateralism – <strong>and</strong> a willingness toresume agricultural trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The EU trade commissi<strong>on</strong>er's recent offer toend export subsidies could be viewed, at least <strong>on</strong> a charitable interpretati<strong>on</strong>, as anotherstep in the right directi<strong>on</strong>. On the other side of the equati<strong>on</strong>, serious <strong>problems</strong> remain.It is <strong>on</strong>e thing for outgoing trade representatives to hint at a new political dynamic.C<strong>on</strong>verting broad pledges into fundamental reform of the 2002 Farm Act or theComm<strong>on</strong> Agricultural Policy (CAP) is likely to prove a very different matter.This paper looks at some of the issues at stake in the Doha Round negotiati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong><strong>agriculture</strong>, <strong>and</strong> at strategies for achieving tangible outcomes that benefit developingcountries. Ultimately, an agreement <strong>on</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> is not an end in itself. It should beviewed as <strong>on</strong>e of the means to the end of reforming the policies that cause globalpoverty. In strategic terms, we argue that stringent disciplines <strong>on</strong> direct <strong>and</strong> indirectexport subsidies, <strong>and</strong> <strong>on</strong> the support systems that generate surpluses, should be theimmediate priority.Such disciplines will require a fundamental departure from the current negotiatingframework – itself a product of the Uruguay Round. The distincti<strong>on</strong> between‘distorting’ <strong>and</strong> ‘n<strong>on</strong>-distorting’ subsidies at the centre of this framework isunworkable <strong>and</strong> unwarranted. It has allowed the EU <strong>and</strong> the US, the architects of theframework, to evade disciplines <strong>on</strong> support <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tinue subsidising over-producti<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> a business-as-usual basis. Subsidy segmentati<strong>on</strong> is another problem. Domesticsupport <strong>and</strong> export subsidies are currently treated as separate categories, whereas theirmarket effects clearly overlap. For example, all payments to sectors in structuralsurplus clearly incorporate an export subsidy comp<strong>on</strong>ent.Special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment is another core theme in this paper. Failure to allowdeveloping countries the policy space to protect their agricultural systems in theinterests of food security would compromise efforts to combat rural poverty. Yetproposals tabled by northern governments advocate a restricti<strong>on</strong> of this space throughimport liberalisati<strong>on</strong>. Leaving aside the hypocrisy implicit in highly protecti<strong>on</strong>ist,heavily subsiding rich countries dem<strong>and</strong>ing market liberalisati<strong>on</strong> in poor <strong>on</strong>es,2


liberalisati<strong>on</strong> in <strong>agriculture</strong> has the potential to inflict grave human developmentcosts. The key requirement for special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment is an acceptance that<strong>on</strong>e size of agricultural agreement does not fit all – <strong>and</strong> that there should be limits tothe reach of multilateral rules.Such an outcome will be difficult to achieve. Increased access to developing countrymarkets is <strong>on</strong>e of the central pillars of agricultural policy in the US - <strong>and</strong> for reas<strong>on</strong>sthat are readily apparent. One c<strong>on</strong>sequence of the structural surplus built into US farmproducti<strong>on</strong> is that access to foreign markets is vital: overall, exports account for <strong>on</strong>equarter of agricultural sales. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to manufacturing, <strong>agriculture</strong> generates a largebalance of payments surplus. Recent trade deals negotiated with the five countries ofthe Central American Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA), the Andean pact countries,<strong>and</strong> Australia, have served to highlight the mercantilist underpinning of US strategy,with a twin emphasis <strong>on</strong> aggressive market opening overseas <strong>and</strong> (witness sugar underCAFTA) limited market access at home. Str<strong>on</strong>g special <strong>and</strong> differential treatmentapplied to a large group of developing countries would clearly rest uneasily with thecommercial imperatives driving US policy - <strong>and</strong> it would provoke oppositi<strong>on</strong> frompowerful domestic producer <strong>and</strong> agribusiness interests.The G20 remains the alliance most likely to deliver an agreement that tackles theinterlocking <strong>problems</strong> facing developing countries. However, it faces formidablechallenges. The ultimate test for any coaliti<strong>on</strong> is not so much whether it advancesshared interest, but the way in which it deals with differences <strong>and</strong> builds bridges toother alliances. Fault lines in the G20 are already clearly visible, not least to EU <strong>and</strong>US negotiators. Differences over preferences, the pace <strong>and</strong> scope of liberalisati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong>over special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment all have the potential to cause c<strong>on</strong>flict <strong>and</strong> toweaken the bargaining power of developing countries. However, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> is a vehiclethrough which developing countries can build pressure for the reform of policies thatare detrimental to their interests, not to menti<strong>on</strong> the interests of most people inindustrialised countries.This paper is organised as follows: Part 1 briefly summarises the <strong>problems</strong> associatedwith Northern agricultural policies. Part 2 turns to some of the issues raised byapproaches to the measurement of agricultural support, focusing <strong>on</strong> the distincti<strong>on</strong>between 'distorting' <strong>and</strong> 'n<strong>on</strong>-distorting' subsidies. Part 3 c<strong>on</strong>siders the implicati<strong>on</strong>s ofsome recent dispute-panel rulings. Part 4 examines issues at the heart of the debate <strong>on</strong>special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment. Part 5 c<strong>on</strong>cludes by reviewing some of the strategicchoices facing developing countries.1. Subsidising poverty: the impact of Northern agricultural policies<strong>on</strong> developing countriesAgricultural trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> are shrouded in a complex legal <strong>and</strong>technical discourse that sometimes obscures the importance of the underlying issues atstake. The outcome of these <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> matters, because it will have an importantbearing <strong>on</strong> the future distributi<strong>on</strong> of benefits in internati<strong>on</strong>al trade – <strong>and</strong> hence <strong>on</strong>patterns of globalisati<strong>on</strong>. More immediately, changes in <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules will define theterms of competiti<strong>on</strong> between the highly capitalised, large-scale agricultural systemsof industrialised countries <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>e side, <strong>and</strong> the smallholder agricultural systems ofpoor countries <strong>on</strong> the other.3


For producers in developing countries, the structure of this competiti<strong>on</strong> matters a greatdeal. Two-thirds of all people surviving <strong>on</strong> less than $1 a day – around 800 milli<strong>on</strong> intotal – live in rural areas, most of them working as smallholder farmers <strong>and</strong>agricultural labourers. The profile of internati<strong>on</strong>al poverty may be increasingly urban,but <strong>on</strong> current trends, the rural share of internati<strong>on</strong>al poverty will remain above 50 percent for the next thirty years. While the rural poor have diverse livelihood structures,they depend critically <strong>on</strong> income generated by the sale of farm products <strong>and</strong> <strong>on</strong>agricultural wages. Agricultural income growth also generates str<strong>on</strong>g multipliereffects bey<strong>on</strong>d <strong>agriculture</strong>. Research by the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Food Policy ResearchInstitute (IFPRI) in sub-Saharan Africa suggests that every $1 generated in theagricultural sector can produce $3 through linkages to other sectors.Such facts explain why, for a large group of developing countries, growth in<strong>agriculture</strong> – especially in the smallholder sector – will c<strong>on</strong>tinue to have adisproporti<strong>on</strong>ate effect <strong>on</strong> poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>.It goes without saying that internati<strong>on</strong>al trade is not the most important factor shapingprospects for rural poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. Export activity can benefit smallholder farmersunder the right c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, but those c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s – which include access to l<strong>and</strong>, credit,<strong>and</strong> marketing infrastructure – are often lacking. This explains why agricultural exportgrowth has been a more powerful force for poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> in Vietnam than Brazil.Domestic policies, not <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules, hold the key to achieving a wider distributi<strong>on</strong> ofbenefits from integrati<strong>on</strong> into global markets. However, <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules matter preciselythey define the space in which domestic policies are formulated.Overall agricultural supportCompetiti<strong>on</strong> between Southern <strong>and</strong> Northern agricultural systems has a bearing <strong>on</strong> themarkets in which many smallholders operate. The terms of that competiti<strong>on</strong> arelargely dictated by the support systems operating in Northern <strong>agriculture</strong>.Measurement of this support is a c<strong>on</strong>troversial exercise – <strong>and</strong> as we show below, <strong>on</strong>ethat has a direct bearing <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Using the OECD's Producer Support Estimate (PSE), overall support for <strong>agriculture</strong> inindustrialised countries amounted to $230bn in 2001, with the EU <strong>and</strong> the USaccounting for two-thirds of the total. Support levels, as measured by the PSE, areequivalent to <strong>on</strong>e third of the value of output in the EU, <strong>and</strong> to <strong>on</strong>e fifth in the US.Bey<strong>on</strong>d these broad headlines, there is ample scope for creative interpretati<strong>on</strong>. Policymakers in the US point out that the EU has a higher overall level of support, <strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong>that this support represents a higher share of the value of output. In retaliati<strong>on</strong>, the EUlikes to highlight the higher per capita support provided to US farmers. The moreimportant point is that US support is more heavily c<strong>on</strong>centrated <strong>on</strong> a narrow range ofproducts, for which the US is a major exporter. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, US subsidies maydistort key internati<strong>on</strong>al markets more than is indicated by simple PSE comparis<strong>on</strong>s.Agricultural support in industrialised countries takes a bewildering variety of forms.Market-price support accounts for around two-thirds of the total, albeit with largevariati<strong>on</strong>s between countries (the US is lower than the EU <strong>on</strong> this count). From aninternati<strong>on</strong>al trade perspective, OECD support is important for a number of reas<strong>on</strong>s.The US is a major exporter of crops such as cereals, rice, <strong>and</strong> cott<strong>on</strong>. Internati<strong>on</strong>al4


world cott<strong>on</strong> prices fell sharply in the sec<strong>on</strong>d half of the 1990s, US producersc<strong>on</strong>tinued to exp<strong>and</strong> producti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> exports, transferring adjustment pressures toother suppliers.Lost shares in world markets Exports facilitated by subsidies artificially exp<strong>and</strong>OECD market shares. In some sectors of c<strong>on</strong>cern to developing countries –including cott<strong>on</strong>, sugar, rice, <strong>and</strong> dairy – subsidized exporters are a majorpresence in the internati<strong>on</strong>al market. Moreover, intra-industrial country trade stillaccounts for almost half of world agricultural trade, roughly the same levels astwo decades ago.Lower prices <strong>and</strong> displacement in domestic markets Ec<strong>on</strong>ometric modelsregister a decline in import prices as a gain in c<strong>on</strong>sumer welfare. However,subsidised OECD exports can produce negative c<strong>on</strong>sequences for rural producersin the importing countries, both through displacement effects <strong>and</strong> as a result oflower prices. These market effects have in turn impacted <strong>on</strong> rural investment <strong>and</strong>wages. At a nati<strong>on</strong>al level, export subsidies can have the effect of c<strong>on</strong>vertingc<strong>on</strong>sumer tastes <strong>and</strong> creating a dependence <strong>on</strong> imports.Ec<strong>on</strong>omic modelling exercises have been widely used to measure the potentialbenefits of liberalisati<strong>on</strong>. Most predict that rich country liberalisati<strong>on</strong> would generatewelfare gains for developing countries, ranging between $8bn in an IMF variant to$40bn in the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Food Policy Research Institute's general equilibrium model.These gains reflect adjustments in internati<strong>on</strong>al prices <strong>and</strong> world market shares.Inevitably, global models reflect large aggregati<strong>on</strong>s that obscure regi<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>aldifferences, as well as distincti<strong>on</strong>s between short-run <strong>and</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g-run effects. Majorexporters st<strong>and</strong> to gain both from the higher prices <strong>and</strong> market share changesassociated with liberalisati<strong>on</strong>, while food importers are predicted to face higher importcosts (<strong>and</strong> associated c<strong>on</strong>sumer welfare losses). Models tend to predict the largestgains for Latin America, with sub-Saharan Africa experiencing small gains or losses.It has to be stressed that most modelling exercises incorporate heroically speculativeassumpti<strong>on</strong>s about price <strong>and</strong> supply elasticities. This weakens their relevance to policymakers grappling with intense debates about the effects of even marginal policyrealignments. So, too, does another c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>. Most modelling exercises point torelatively small aggregate gains for developing countries resulting from sweeping, <strong>and</strong>arguably implausible, liberalisati<strong>on</strong> scenarios in industrialised countries. For example,the IMF model predicts that full agricultural policy liberalisati<strong>on</strong> in industrialisedcountries would raise developing country GDP by 0.1 per cent - not a scenario likelyto prompt urgent acti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the part of G8 leaders.N<strong>on</strong>e of this deflects from the real <strong>problems</strong> caused by industrial country policies. Aswith any large aggregati<strong>on</strong>, net outcomes obscure <strong>problems</strong> facing countries in thesample – <strong>and</strong> some countries <strong>and</strong> groups of producers face very large losses indeed. Interms of foreign exchange costs, OECD support systems inflict the highest costs <strong>on</strong>major exporters. For example, Argentina loses heavily in the cereals sector, <strong>and</strong> EUsugar policies cost Brazil in excess of $400m annually. Countries such as Viet Nam<strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong> also suffer losses in exports of rice – a crop grown predominantly bysmall farmers.6


Countries in sub-Saharan Africa are not immune to the effects of OECD policies. Inthe case of cott<strong>on</strong>, the regi<strong>on</strong> suffers both market displacement <strong>and</strong> price-reducti<strong>on</strong>effects.The background to this case is well known, but bears repetiti<strong>on</strong>. US support for itscott<strong>on</strong> producers in 2000/01 amounted to just under $4bn – an amount comparable tothe market value of output. Because the US accounts for around <strong>on</strong>e quarter of worldexports of cott<strong>on</strong>, its domestic support has global market c<strong>on</strong>sequences. According tothe Internati<strong>on</strong>al Cott<strong>on</strong> Advisory Committee, that support has lowered world pricesby around <strong>on</strong>e quarter. For countries such as Burkina Faso, Benin, <strong>and</strong> Mali, wherecott<strong>on</strong> accounts for around <strong>on</strong>e third of exports, the implied costs in terms of foreignexchange losses are very high; they are estimated at $200m for 2001. The impact <strong>on</strong>household income for the 10 to 11 milli<strong>on</strong> smallholders involved in growing cott<strong>on</strong> ismore difficult to establish. However, household-income data for Benin suggests thatthe decline in the world price caused by US subsidies is correlated with a 12 per centincrease in poverty, pushing an additi<strong>on</strong>al 250,000 people below the nati<strong>on</strong>al povertyline. To put US subsidies into perspective, they exceed the total GDP of countries likeBurkina Faso <strong>and</strong> Mali.Several case studies have highlighted the impact of subsidised Northern agriculturalexports <strong>on</strong> local markets. During the 1990s, import liberalisati<strong>on</strong> exposed agriculturalproducers in a growing number of developing countries to competiti<strong>on</strong> fromsubsidised imports. In Mexico, liberalisati<strong>on</strong> under NAFTA has resulted in a sustainedincrease in imports of maize – a crop grown by around 2.4 milli<strong>on</strong> Mexicansmallholder farmers. Agricultural policy makers in the US herald this as a triumph formarket efficiency. But US maize growers received $6bn in direct payments in 2001,an amount equivalent to five times the federal agricultural budget for Mexico.Smallholder maize farmers in Mexico have suffered lower prices <strong>and</strong> marketdisplacement.In some cases, import liberalisati<strong>on</strong> has led directly to a surge in heavily subsidisedimports <strong>and</strong> attendant market disrupti<strong>on</strong>. This was the case in the rice sector in Haitiin 1995 (facilitated by IMF loan c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s requiring rapid import liberalisati<strong>on</strong>) <strong>and</strong>in the Indian dairy sector in 1997. For a larger group of developing countries, importshave climbed steadily over time. The FAO estimates that food imports now accountfor 10 to 12 per cent of the calorific intake of Least Developed Countries, <strong>and</strong> that thefood-import bill now represents over three per cent of their GDP. While theunderlying causes of this increase in dependence <strong>on</strong> food imports are complex <strong>and</strong>varied, the disincentives for local investment created by export subsidies are a factorof c<strong>on</strong>siderable importance. In terms of food security, the chr<strong>on</strong>ic balance-ofpayments<strong>problems</strong> facing a number of low-income countries makes them highlyvulnerable to risks associated with periods of high prices.Trade preferencesTrade preferences add another dimensi<strong>on</strong> of complexity to North–South agriculturaltrade relati<strong>on</strong>s. Tariffs <strong>and</strong> quotas introduce a wedge between world prices <strong>and</strong> OECDdomestic prices. In principle, preferential schemes allow suppliers in beneficiarycountries to access part of the price premium, effectively raising the rate of return <strong>on</strong>7


investment. In practice, the benefits of preferences are diminished through complexentry systems <strong>and</strong> eligibility requirements.Some of the <strong>problems</strong> are well known. Under many schemes – such as AGOA –preferences can be withdrawn at any time. Product coverage is often limited, asreflected in regi<strong>on</strong>al trade agreements. Mercosur exporters face agricultural tariffs inthe EU that are 50 per cent higher than those faced by the EU in its exports tocountries in the group. Preferences over MFN rates are minimal. As in otherarrangements, the EU prefers to c<strong>on</strong>centrate its preferences <strong>on</strong> products that it doesnot produce - or <strong>on</strong> countries that lack the capacity to take advantage of marketopportunities. Regulati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cerning the origin of items eligible for preferences areanother factor limiting the ability of would-be suppliers to fill quotas. An additi<strong>on</strong>alproblem is that preferences can lock countries into producti<strong>on</strong> in areas where theyhave limited comparative advantage, exposing them to future risks.Such c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s have prompted the World Bank <strong>and</strong> others to take a dim view ofpreferential trade. There is no shortage of ec<strong>on</strong>omic models purporting to show that,in aggregate <strong>and</strong> over the l<strong>on</strong>g-run, preferences hurt their putative beneficiaries. Notsurprisingly, the beneficiaries themselves take a different view. African <strong>and</strong> Caribbeanexporters of sugar to the EU receive a price some three times above the average worldmarket price for a fixed quota of sugar. In the absence of preferences, many sugarindustries would either c<strong>on</strong>tract or collapse. Similarly, tariff preferences under the EUCot<strong>on</strong>ou agreement provide important advantages to Africa. Governments in theregi<strong>on</strong> see the agreement as vital to protecti<strong>on</strong> against competiti<strong>on</strong> from LatinAmerica. For negotiators representing countries with preferences at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>,preference erosi<strong>on</strong> can pose a real <strong>and</strong> immediate threat to export markets. That threatis likely to weigh more heavily in the design of trade policy than the results ofec<strong>on</strong>omic modelling exercises.2. Measuring support under the Agreement <strong>on</strong> AgriculturePrior to the Uruguay Round, multilateral rules were of limited relevance toagricultural trade. The Agreement <strong>on</strong> Agriculture (AoA) started to change this picture,introducing for the first time a framework of rules <strong>and</strong> disciplines to limit support.The Doha Round <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> operate within the parameters of the AoA.Unfortunately, this starting point severely disadvantages developing countries.The AoA suffers from two fundamental flaws. First, it is enshrines an arbitrarydistincti<strong>on</strong> between 'distorting' <strong>and</strong> 'n<strong>on</strong>-distorting' support. Initially developed underthe Blair House accord between the EU <strong>and</strong> the US, this distincti<strong>on</strong> has enabled thesubsidy superpowers to evade disciplines <strong>on</strong> supports that damage developing countryinterests. The sec<strong>on</strong>d, more fundamental, problem can be traced to the tripartitestructure of the AoA framework. Under this framework, domestic support, exportsubsidies, <strong>and</strong> market access are treated as segmented units. This is unfortunate,because the distincti<strong>on</strong> between export subsidies <strong>and</strong> domestic supports is increasinglyblurred.When is a subsidy not a subsidy?8


The m<strong>and</strong>ate of the Doha Round mirrors the provisi<strong>on</strong>s of the AoA. Governments areexpected to deliver the following outcomes:‘Substantial reducti<strong>on</strong>s of trade distorting domestic support’‘Reducti<strong>on</strong>s of, with a view to phasing out, all forms of export subsidies’‘Substantial improvements in market access’The term 'trade distorting' is of more than passing relevance in applicati<strong>on</strong> to domesticsupport. Earlier we used the PSE as an indicator of overall levels of support to OECD<strong>agriculture</strong>. For the purposes of <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>, a different measure is used: theAggregate Measure of Support (AMS). In nominal terms, the AMS is supposed tocapture 'trade distorting' subsidies. Under the AoA, a ceiling is set in AMS terms at$21bn for the US <strong>and</strong> $19.8bn for the EU.The subsidy 'box' system is supposed to reflect the differentiati<strong>on</strong> of subsidies. Alldomestic-support measures deemed to distort producti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> trade fall into the‘Amber Box’. Under the Uruguay Round AoA, these are subsidies that have to be cut,subject to a provisi<strong>on</strong> known as the 'de minimis' arrangement. Under the terms of thelatter, Northern governments can provide financing up to the equivalent of five percent of the value of producti<strong>on</strong> (the figure is 10 per cent for developing countries).Export subsidies also fit into the category of AMS support, subject to limits <strong>and</strong>reducti<strong>on</strong>s. Under the terms of the Uruguay Round, the EU <strong>and</strong> the US are required tokeep the AMS below a specified ceiling. The rate at which the ceiling is lowered inthe years <strong>ahead</strong> will depend <strong>on</strong> the outcome of the Doha Round <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>.The ‘Blue Box’ can be thought of as the Amber Box with c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. Support thatwould normally be placed in the Amber Box can be placed in the Blue Box if it islinked to a programme designed to limit producti<strong>on</strong>. An example of such aprogramme is the EU's set-aside arrangement, first introduced under the 1992 reforms.There are no limits <strong>on</strong> the amount of support that can be provided under the Blue Box– an issue that figures prominently in current <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>.The ‘Green Box’ is defined in Annex 2 of the AoA. In order to qualify for thiscategory, subsidies should either not distort trade at all, or cause minimal distorti<strong>on</strong>.Green Box subsidies can be provided without limit.What is the relevance of all this for <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> to change Northern agriculturalpolicies that cause over-producti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> facilitate export subsidisati<strong>on</strong>? Figure 1 offersa partial answer. It provides a breakdown of support categories for the EU <strong>and</strong> the USfor the marketing year 1999, the last year for which official reports are available.9


What emerges from the data is that the EU <strong>and</strong> the US have complied with the letterof the AoA. In 1999, both were operating well within the bounds of their AMSceilings. For the EU, combined Amber Box <strong>and</strong> export subsidies represented 76 percent of the AMS ceiling, rising to 84 per cent for the US. However, Figure 1 alsodem<strong>on</strong>strates that compliance with the AoA has been achieved through a process ofsubsidy shifting, or the transfer of support into the Green Box <strong>and</strong> the Blue Box. Inthe case of the US, supports subject to <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> disciplines represented <strong>on</strong>ly 22 per centof overall support, rising to 69 per cent for the EU. For developing countriesc<strong>on</strong>cerned with the trade distorting effects of agricultural support, this raises anobvious questi<strong>on</strong>: namely, are the n<strong>on</strong>-disciplined supports genuinely n<strong>on</strong>-distorting?The current state of research does not allow this questi<strong>on</strong> to be answered with anyaccuracy. Financial transfers linked to historic producti<strong>on</strong> levels rather than currentoutput (<strong>on</strong>e of the criteria used for decoupled payments) provide capital <strong>and</strong> anincreased level of security against risks posed by price fluctuati<strong>on</strong>s. To the extent thatpayments are linked to l<strong>and</strong>, they inflate l<strong>and</strong> values <strong>and</strong> hence borrowing capacity. Byc<strong>on</strong>trast, other transfers linked to envir<strong>on</strong>mental policy goals may have far weakermarket effects. Unfortunately, the current system of categorisati<strong>on</strong>, delays in EU <strong>and</strong>US reporting to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>, <strong>and</strong> the limited relevance of either the AMS or the PSE asindicators, leaves developing countries with limited leverage bey<strong>on</strong>d the disputesettlement system for challenging northern government practices.Domestic policy reform agendasAgreements at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> reflect a dynamic interacti<strong>on</strong> between domestic reformstrategies <strong>and</strong> trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>. There are complex feedback loops c<strong>on</strong>necting10


positi<strong>on</strong>s adopted at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>and</strong> the development of domestic policies. Nowhere isthis process more evident than in <strong>agriculture</strong>. Domestic policies are c<strong>on</strong>tested bypowerful interest groups, many of which operate through political associati<strong>on</strong>sstructured around the maintenance of access to subsidies <strong>and</strong> rent-seeking. Northerngovernments are inevitably c<strong>on</strong>strained by the effectiveness of these associati<strong>on</strong>s. Atthe same time, they have to balance wider objectives – such as agreements in n<strong>on</strong>agriculturalareas <strong>and</strong> the development of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> system itself – against the claimsof vested interest groups.The imprint of domestic policies <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> agreements is much in evidence, notablywith regard to US policies. At the time of the Uruguay Round, a large share of USsupport was directed towards programmes incorporating (largely unsuccessful) supplymanagement requirements. The 1992 CAP reforms took the EU in the same directi<strong>on</strong>.Both parties had an interest in a provisi<strong>on</strong> that maximised flexibility in this area <strong>and</strong>minimised multilateral c<strong>on</strong>straints – hence the Blue Box. Having moved towardsmore ‘decoupled’ payments – a process that gathered pace with the 1996 FederalAgricultural Improvement Act (FAIR) – the US had an interest in even weakerdisciplines in this area, which were duly catered for with the Green Box.The important point here is that subsidy re-ordering <strong>and</strong> reclassificati<strong>on</strong> enabled theEU <strong>and</strong> the US to make deep cuts in their respective AMS levels with minimaladjustment. Measured by reference to the PSE, both parties increased support between1986-1998 (the reference period for Uruguay Round subsidy reducti<strong>on</strong>) <strong>and</strong> 2000.When it comes to agricultural <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>, measurement matters a greatdeal. Bey<strong>on</strong>d the complex technical <strong>problems</strong> involved, developing countries have astr<strong>on</strong>g interest in preventing a Doha round outcome that accommodates another boutof subsidy repackaging. This in turn will require an underst<strong>and</strong>ing of how theparameters of domestic reform debates in the EU <strong>and</strong> the US play out at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>.The current directi<strong>on</strong> of reform poses both threats <strong>and</strong> opportunities. In the case of theUS, the 2002 Farm Act accelerates a move back from the decoupling model adoptedin 1996. The move started with the expansi<strong>on</strong> of 'emergency payments' <strong>and</strong> anincrease in market-price support payments in resp<strong>on</strong>se to low world prices at the endof the 1990s. N<strong>on</strong>-decoupled output-based payments increased from $1.6bn annuallyfor 1996–98 to $9bn in 1999–2001. The 2002 Farm Act legislati<strong>on</strong> increases loanrates (in effect, minimum guaranteed prices), updates the acreage <strong>and</strong> yields <strong>on</strong> whichdirect payments are based, <strong>and</strong> instituti<strong>on</strong>alises a system of counter-cyclical payments.One upshot is that the US is now almost certainly pushing close to its AMS ceiling,creating str<strong>on</strong>g incentives to either limit ceiling reducti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> weaken disciplines <strong>on</strong>direct payments.Just how close the US is to the ceiling is uncertain, since the status of many of thesepayments remains uncertain. The structure of payments for 2003 in summarised inFigure 2. An immediate problem for policy makers in the US is that the 2002 FarmAct may have been leveraged previously Green Box support into the Amber Box, inwhich case their ceiling has already been exceeded. Even before the new legislati<strong>on</strong>,low world prices were pushing the US closer to its AMS ceiling. Were prices to fallagain, the provisi<strong>on</strong>s of the 2002 Farm Act would almost certainly generate supportlevels above the ceiling. Apart from restricting the room for manoeuvre, this impliesthat an agreement at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> will require major legislative reform in C<strong>on</strong>gress. US11


negotiators at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> are likely to seek a high level of flexibility in the definiti<strong>on</strong> ofthe Green Box <strong>and</strong> to keep open the possibility of recourse to the Blue Box, possiblywith reference to counter-cyclical payments.In the EU, the ambiti<strong>on</strong> of CAP reformers has been to shift support into the GreenBox through full decoupling. Differences between member States have limitedprogress, resulting in a (very) partial decoupling under the June 2003 reforms.Meanwhile, <strong>on</strong>e major sector – sugar – is as yet unreformed. Translated into <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>strategy, the parameters of CAP reform dictate that the EU is likely to drive a hardbargain in seeking to maintain the Blue Box <strong>and</strong> a residual right to subsidise directlyexports in key sectors.Any agreement in the Doha round will incorporate provisi<strong>on</strong>s for ‘decoupled’ support– <strong>and</strong> rightly so. It would be politically unrealistic <strong>and</strong> socially undesirable to arguefor the eliminati<strong>on</strong> of northern government support in area where there is a clearpublic policy interest. For developing countries the key questi<strong>on</strong> is what c<strong>on</strong>stitutes‘decoupled’ support <strong>and</strong>, by extensi<strong>on</strong>, what is eligible for the Green Box. This is anarea in which more research <strong>and</strong> a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the market effects ofpolicies is vital. What is clear, however, is that much of the support currently directedinto the Green Box does damage the interests of developing countries.Export subsidies <strong>and</strong> export dumping12


From the perspective of developing countries, <strong>and</strong> – more importantly – theiragricultural producers, the classificati<strong>on</strong> of subsidies at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> is of less relevancethan their effects <strong>on</strong> markets. Export subsidies represent a major source of c<strong>on</strong>cern,since they are widely regarded as being am<strong>on</strong>g the most damaging. With the shift instructure of Northern support, the distincti<strong>on</strong> between export subsidies <strong>and</strong> domesticsupport is becoming increasingly artificial.This problem can be dem<strong>on</strong>strated by reference to Figure 1, which shows that, for thepurposes of <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> classificati<strong>on</strong>, the US was a n<strong>on</strong>-subsidising exporter at the end ofthe 1990s – <strong>and</strong> this remains the case. The EU accounted for over 90 per cent ofOECD export subsidies in 1999. However, even then they represented a relativelysmall comp<strong>on</strong>ent of overall support; <strong>and</strong> that comp<strong>on</strong>ent has been shrinking since1999. Cuts in guaranteed domestic prices allied to increases in world prices haveenabled the EU to export at prices above domestic levels. Only two major sectors –sugar <strong>and</strong> dairy – now c<strong>on</strong>sistently depend <strong>on</strong> direct export subsidies.The word 'direct' is operative in this c<strong>on</strong>text. Both the US <strong>and</strong> the EU provide veryhigh levels of support to sectors that are in structural surplus. Indeed, in many sectors,these surpluses would not exist in the absence of direct payments to farmers. Itfollows that direct payments include a de facto export subsidy, even though they arenot reported as such de jure for <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> purposes.The problem can best be dem<strong>on</strong>strated by reference to specific commodities. Menti<strong>on</strong>has already been made of the $4bn in direct payments allocated to cott<strong>on</strong> producers. Interms of <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> reporting, <strong>on</strong>ly around two per cent of these payments can becategorised as export subsidies. Yet in the absence of direct payments, US exportactivity in cott<strong>on</strong> would be much diminished for an obvious reas<strong>on</strong>: in most yearsaverage producti<strong>on</strong> costs c<strong>on</strong>siderably exceed world prices. Under n<strong>on</strong>-subsidisedc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, cott<strong>on</strong> would not be a profitable crop for the vast majority of USproducers. Cott<strong>on</strong> is not unique. In the case of rice, the OECD estimates US supportto be equivalent to just under half of the value of output. Around <strong>on</strong>e third ofproducti<strong>on</strong> is exported, again without the help of export subsidies. Similar c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sprevail in maize <strong>and</strong> wheat. The point in all of these cases is that direct paymentsclearly spill over into export subsidies, though they are treated purely as domesticsupports for <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> purposes.In the interests of balance, it has to be acknowledged that the hidden export subsidiesat work in the EU are <strong>on</strong> a larger scale than those applied in the US. One way ofcapturing this scale is to adopt the simple expedient of dividing the volume of outputin any sector by the value of direct payments. This creates a unit value of subsidymeasure, which can in turn by c<strong>on</strong>verted into an export subsidy by reference to exportvolume. On this measure, the EU provides an export subsidy of around $610m for2001. However, no official export subsidies were recorded in this year, underliningthe limited nature of the current reporting regime.The sugar sector in the EU provides an even more telling example. Europe is theworld's sec<strong>on</strong>d largest exporter of sugar after Brazil, supplying around five milli<strong>on</strong>t<strong>on</strong>nes annually to the world market. These exports are sustained <strong>on</strong> an annual basis,even though guaranteed prices under the CAP are some four times world market13


prices (Figure 3). As the EU’s own Court of Auditors has acknowledged, there wouldbe no European sugar exports in the absence of subsidies. Yet the EU admits tosubsidising around <strong>on</strong>e half of total exports. It maintains that the other half is n<strong>on</strong>subsidisedor, more accurately, 'self-financed' through a levy paid by producers – anargument now under challenge in a <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> dispute panel (see below).The Institute for Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Trade Policy (ITAP) <strong>and</strong> others have helped tohighlight the problem by focusing <strong>on</strong> the gap between export prices <strong>and</strong> cost ofproducti<strong>on</strong>. Under <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules, dumping is broadly defined as the sale overseas of aproduct at prices below the normal price prevailing <strong>on</strong> the domestic market. However,in cases where 'normal price' is impossible to establish, importers can c<strong>on</strong>struct value<strong>on</strong> the basis of cost-of-producti<strong>on</strong> criteria. Using these criteria, it is clear that the USis dumping without export subsidies <strong>on</strong> a large scale: export prices for cott<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong>wheat in 2003 were respectively around 50 per cent <strong>and</strong> 20 per cent of averageproducti<strong>on</strong> costs. In the case of EU sugar, the dumping margin measured as the gapbetween producti<strong>on</strong> costs <strong>and</strong> export price would be in the range 300–350 per cent.Were the Indian textiles industry to attempt exporting to the EU or the US <strong>on</strong> similarterms, it could c<strong>on</strong>fidently predict a swift resp<strong>on</strong>se in the form of a barrage of antidumpingacti<strong>on</strong>s. Yet when it comes to <strong>agriculture</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules allow the EU <strong>and</strong> theUS to dump with something close to impunity.Existing rules <strong>on</strong> export subsidies suffer from limitati<strong>on</strong>s in two further areas. First,they do not cover export-credit programmes – the principle form of direct exportsubsidisati<strong>on</strong> in the US. While the EU accounts for the bulk of direct export subsidies,the US accounts for the li<strong>on</strong>'s share of export credits. The GSM 102 <strong>and</strong> the GSM 103programmes <strong>and</strong> the Supplier Credit Programme provide for financing of around$5.5bn. These programmes are explicitly aimed at creating <strong>and</strong> maintainingcommercial market outlets for US surpluses. They are extensively deployed incountries ranging from the Philippines to Mexico <strong>and</strong> West Africa. Depending <strong>on</strong> the14


method used to calculate c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>ality, the subsidy comp<strong>on</strong>ent of these programmesis between $500m <strong>and</strong> $700m annually. The <strong>on</strong>ly internati<strong>on</strong>al rules in operati<strong>on</strong> are aset of best-endeavour clauses in what are largely unobserved OECD guidelines.The sec<strong>on</strong>d gap in <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules relates to food aid. US food aid programmes havedeveloped in large measure as a surplus-disposal policy, geared towards the creati<strong>on</strong>of commercial markets. This remains <strong>on</strong>e of the core objectives of Title 1 of PL 480,under which eligible countries must 'dem<strong>on</strong>strate the potential to become commercialmarkets for US agricultural commodities'. The commercialised nature of Title 1 isapparent at a number of levels. Countries facing genuine food emergencies in southern<strong>and</strong> eastern Africa c<strong>on</strong>sistently receive less than do commercial market outlets.Moreover, US food aid transfers fall when world prices rise – the opposite of whatmight be expected under a dem<strong>and</strong>-driven programme. Current budget authorisati<strong>on</strong>sfor Title 1 amount to $176m annually, much of which could be categorised as exportsubsidies. For example, in 2001, Archer Daniel Midl<strong>and</strong>, <strong>on</strong>e of the world's largestgrain traders, was awarded $35m in Title 1 c<strong>on</strong>tracts to supply corn <strong>and</strong> rice to thePhilippines.Market accessNegotiati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> market access represent the third pillar of the Doha m<strong>and</strong>ate. Onceagain, the shadow of the Uruguay Round looms large. The agreement reached wasdesigned to facilitate evasi<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> limit adjustment costs <strong>on</strong> the part of industrialisedcountries. One of the central c<strong>on</strong>cerns for developing countries is to avoid a repeatperformance.Under the AoA, governments were required to reduce average tariffs <strong>on</strong> a linear basis– the so-called Uruguay Round formula. The aggregate nature of the tariff-cuttingformula gave countries a great deal of flexibility. Large tariff reducti<strong>on</strong>s forcommodities representing a small share of trade could be used to facilitate farshallower tariff cuts for commodities representing a larger share of trade. In fact, thehigh tariffs in operati<strong>on</strong> during the reference years enabled most countries to meettheir AoA commitments without difficulty.In the Doha Round, debate has centred <strong>on</strong> the formula to be used for cutting tariffs.The 'friends of the Uruguay Round formula' group – which includes the EU, prefers alinear approach. Most developing countries – backed, with some reservati<strong>on</strong>s, by theUS – want to have tariff cuts that escalate with the size of the initial tariff; the Swissformula approach, as it is known. The aim is to create tariff c<strong>on</strong>vergence at arelatively low level, <strong>and</strong> to eliminate tariff peaks.Most formulae envisaged for the Doha Round are a blend of the two approaches. Asexpressed in the Derbez text (the last under c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> before the collapse of theCancun summit) this would segregate tariffs into three groups. For <strong>on</strong>e, average tariffcuts would be applied with a minimum for each tariff line. For another, higher tariffswould be lowered proporti<strong>on</strong>ately more than lower tariffs, <strong>and</strong> a tariff ceiling wouldbe applied; remaining tariffs would be eliminated. The progressivity of the reducti<strong>on</strong>would be determined by a coefficient. For the final group in the Derbez proposal,tariffs would be eliminated.15


The broad c<strong>on</strong>sensus is that a cocktail approach is needed. Bey<strong>on</strong>d this starting point,there are deep divisi<strong>on</strong>s. One of the <strong>problems</strong> with the Derbez text is that it leavesroom for creative evasi<strong>on</strong>. Northern governments could apply the Swiss formula <strong>on</strong>tariffs that are already relatively low, <strong>and</strong> the linear Uruguay Round formula forhigher tariffs, creating ample scope for the maintenance of tariff peaks. [These issuesare dealt with in more detail in the background paper by Panos K<strong>on</strong><strong>and</strong>reas.]3. <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> dispute-panel rulings<str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> case law has become an increasingly important factor in shaping the negotiatingenvir<strong>on</strong>ment. With the expiry of the Peace Clause, principles established in disputepanelrulings now c<strong>on</strong>strain the opti<strong>on</strong>s open to Northern policy makers in <strong>agriculture</strong>– <strong>and</strong> they could strengthen the h<strong>and</strong>s of developing country negotiators. Three suchcases merit special attenti<strong>on</strong>.The Brazil–US cott<strong>on</strong> ruling The interim report <strong>on</strong> the ruling has not yet been madepublic. However, some of the decisi<strong>on</strong>s are now well known. Perhaps the mostimportant is that Producti<strong>on</strong> Flexibility C<strong>on</strong>tract support <strong>and</strong>, by extensi<strong>on</strong>, DirectPayments are n<strong>on</strong>-Green Box, <strong>and</strong> therefore not exempt from subsidy reducti<strong>on</strong>s. Itmay well be that, if applied to other sectors, the ruling would place the US in breachof its AMS ceiling. Whether or not this is the case, the US is now highly vulnerable todispute cases in other areas, even for periods covered by the Peace Clause. The Paneldecided that US subsidies could not benefit from Peace Clause protecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> thegrounds that the level of support exceeded the amount provided in the base year. Withregard to export subsidies, the Panel found against the US <strong>on</strong> two counts. First, it hasruled that a cott<strong>on</strong>-specific credit programme – the Step 2 programme – c<strong>on</strong>stitutes aprohibited subsidy. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, <strong>and</strong> more importantly, it has ruled that the GSM <strong>and</strong> otherexport-credit programmes circumvent US export-subsidy commitment not just incott<strong>on</strong>, but also in soybeans, fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetables, <strong>and</strong> rice. Finally, the Panel has ruledthat US cott<strong>on</strong> subsidies cause significant price depressi<strong>on</strong> in world markets <strong>and</strong> in theBrazilian market. For various technical reas<strong>on</strong>s, the Panel found against the claimsthat (i) US subsidies artificially increase US world market share <strong>and</strong> (ii) that subsidiesenable the US to capture an inequitable market share (in the sense stipulated in theGATT Article XV1 subsidy code).The Brazil, Thail<strong>and</strong>, Australia–EU sugar dispute Behind the legal complexities ofthis case, the central issue at stake is the definiti<strong>on</strong> of an export subsidy. The EUclaims that two categories of its sugar exports are n<strong>on</strong>-subsidised. Under the firstcategory are the 1.2m t<strong>on</strong>nes exported through a levy <strong>on</strong> guaranteed prices paid toprocessors. In the view of the EU, the levy makes the exports 'self-financing'. Viewedfrom a different perspective, the levy itself is a mechanism for diverting part of ac<strong>on</strong>sumer transfer to the industry into a disguised export subsidy. Such arrangementsare prohibited under Article 9 of the AoA – <strong>and</strong> the EU has put up at best a weakdefence in the dispute panel. The sec<strong>on</strong>d category of exports c<strong>on</strong>cerns n<strong>on</strong>-quotasugar, or producti<strong>on</strong> that is not subject to price support. In effect, these exports arefinanced through a cross-subsidy from quota sugar. Support prices for quota sugarmake it possible for producers to cover their fixed costs, with world prices coveringmarginal costs. The Court of Auditors of the EU has c<strong>on</strong>ceded that exports of n<strong>on</strong>subsidisedsugar would not be feasible with a transfer of subsidies from quota sugar. If16


the EU loses the case at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>, it will recast the entire CAP reform debate as itrelates to sugar, <strong>and</strong> raise questi<strong>on</strong>s about cross-subsidies in other sectors.Canadian dairy dispute This case has set a precedent of direct relevance to the EUsugar sector. In it, the Dispute Panel ruled that domestic support applied to products insurplus can have the same effects as export subsidies. To cite part of the report, ‘Wec<strong>on</strong>sider that the distincti<strong>on</strong> between domestic support <strong>and</strong> export subsidy disciplineswould be eroded if <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> members were entitled to use domestic support without limitto provide support for exports.’ This would appear to create a precedent for the EUsugar case. More generally, as with the Brazil–US cott<strong>on</strong> rulings, a <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> DisputePanel has, in effect, challenged some of the central assumpti<strong>on</strong>s underpinning theAoA.4. Special <strong>and</strong> differential treatmentThe Doha m<strong>and</strong>ate clearly establishes special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment as a priorityfor the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> trade round. In the Derbez text, this is interpreted <strong>on</strong> the modelestablished in the Uruguay Round, namely, 'same directi<strong>on</strong>, different speed'. In<strong>agriculture</strong>, as in other areas, developing countries are broadly expected to follow thesame reform path as industrialised countries, but over a l<strong>on</strong>ger time-frame, withshallower tariff cuts <strong>and</strong> exempti<strong>on</strong>s for some forms of support from reducti<strong>on</strong>commitments. However, the critical importance of <strong>agriculture</strong> to food security <strong>and</strong>poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> raises important questi<strong>on</strong>s about the role <strong>and</strong> scope of <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules.Market accessMuch of the debate <strong>on</strong> special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment in <strong>agriculture</strong> has focused <strong>on</strong>the theme of market access. The approaches adopted by different governments serveto illustrate the complexities of the issues at stake, not least for the G20 group.In the strategic visi<strong>on</strong> of US negotiators, the aim of the Doha Round is to advance anaggressive movement towards trade liberalisati<strong>on</strong> that extends bey<strong>on</strong>d the borders ofdeveloped countries. To cite the letter of Robert Zoellick, the US TradeRepresentative, to trade ministers in January 2004: ‘For the United States, the degreeof ambiti<strong>on</strong> is linked to ... a substantial increase in real market access opportunitiesboth in developed <strong>and</strong> major developing country markets.’ Applicati<strong>on</strong> of the Swissformula, in the US view, should not be limited to industrialised country <strong>agriculture</strong>.The US emphasis <strong>on</strong> market opening at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> is a multilateral extensi<strong>on</strong> of a widerstrategic visi<strong>on</strong> for <strong>agriculture</strong>. Menti<strong>on</strong> has already been made of the acutedependence of US farm incomes <strong>on</strong> access to overseas markets. Bey<strong>on</strong>d the farmsector, agricultural exports play a critical macro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic role. The $10-20bn annualsurplus posted <strong>on</strong> agricultural trade helps to offset deficits in other areas. As even acursory tour of the USTR web-site will dem<strong>on</strong>strate, policy makers regard increasedaccess to developing country markets as a vital objective.In this c<strong>on</strong>text, NAFTA is held up as something of a model. Import liberalisati<strong>on</strong> inMexico led to an eighteen-fold increase in US maize exports from 1993-2000, withthe overall value of agricultural exports doubling. The recently negotiated agreementwith the five CAFTA countries (Costa Rica, Guatemala, El Salvador, H<strong>on</strong>duras, <strong>and</strong>17


Nicaragua) provides for extensive market opening opportunities, with more than halfof US agricultural exports now entering markets duty free <strong>and</strong> a fifteen-ear phase-outperiod for remaining tariffs. On the import side, C<strong>on</strong>gressi<strong>on</strong>al oppositi<strong>on</strong> has limitedUS c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s. Both under CAFTA <strong>and</strong> the bilateral agreement with Australia, theUS has maintained stringent import quotas <strong>on</strong> products such as sugar, beef <strong>and</strong> dairy,<strong>and</strong> prohibitive tariffs above quota. When it comes to agricultural trade, mercantilismis alive, well, <strong>and</strong> kicking in the US.The form taken by this mercantilism has direct implicati<strong>on</strong>s for special <strong>and</strong>differential treatment. Implicit in the USTR’s formulati<strong>on</strong> is a distincti<strong>on</strong> betweencountries that represent major commercial markets <strong>and</strong> the rest – a radical newapproach to the classificati<strong>on</strong> of developing countries for purposes of special <strong>and</strong>differential treatment. It might not unreas<strong>on</strong>ably be assumed that the 'major market'group extends from low-income countries (including India <strong>and</strong> China), to middleincomecountries (including Brazil <strong>and</strong> other Latin American countries, much ofNorth Africa, <strong>and</strong> south-east Asia), <strong>and</strong> a large group of food importing developingcountries. This is precisely the c<strong>on</strong>stituency that the US Department of Agriculture isanxious to cultivate for commercial market development.Some support for the US view has come from other sources. The World Bank hasargued that developing countries should accept the case for import liberalisati<strong>on</strong> in<strong>agriculture</strong>, while acknowledging that instituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straints may undermine thebenefits of openness in low-income countries. Like the US, the Bank argues forgreater differentiati<strong>on</strong> between countries. Middle-income countries, so the argumentruns, need to accept less protecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> weaker special <strong>and</strong> differential treatmentprovisi<strong>on</strong>s. With two major excepti<strong>on</strong>s, low-income countries would enjoy a higherorder of special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment. The two excepti<strong>on</strong>s in questi<strong>on</strong> are India<strong>and</strong> China, apparently <strong>on</strong> the basis of market size <strong>and</strong> what the World Bank sees as<str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> realpolitik – a euphemism, in this c<strong>on</strong>text, for what is acceptable to the EU <strong>and</strong>the US.It has to be emphasised that the debate over special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment raisesmatters of fundamental importance for agricultural trade policy formulati<strong>on</strong> indeveloping countries. Nowhere is this more apparent than with regard to marketaccess. Applicati<strong>on</strong> of the Swiss formula to developing countries, as envisaged by theUS, would entail very deep tariff cuts, implying potentially large shifts in relativeprices between imports <strong>and</strong> domestically produced goods. The aim of the Swissformula is to produce a narrow range of final tariffs from a wide set of initial tariffs,<strong>and</strong> to arrive at a tariff ceiling. The rate of c<strong>on</strong>vergence is decided by the coefficientused in the formula – a subject of intense c<strong>on</strong>troversy. 1 Figure 4 provides <strong>on</strong>e possiblescenario, using a Swiss-formula coefficient of 25. It shows that countries such as Indiawould be faced with c<strong>on</strong>siderable adjustments.1The Swiss formula is as follows Z = CX/C+X. Where Z equals the final tariff, X the initial tariff,<strong>and</strong> C the coefficient.18


Figure 4 also draws attenti<strong>on</strong> to another important aspect of the debate <strong>on</strong> marketaccess as it relates to special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment: the gap between bound tariffs(the legally binding ceiling in <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> schedules) <strong>and</strong> applied tariffs (the tariffs thatgovernments actually charge). For some developing countries, this gap is relativelylarge. If the benchmark for tariff cuts is the bound rate, this offers some flexibility –especially if countries have bound at high levels. However, <strong>on</strong>e country – the US –has argued that <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> to lower tariffs should start from applied tariffs, breakingwith the traditi<strong>on</strong> of all previous rounds. Wherever the benchmark is set, somecountries will face acute <strong>problems</strong>. This includes those (such as Brazil, Peru, thePhilippines, <strong>and</strong> Egypt) that have bound tariffs at relatively low levels, especiallywhere bound rates are close to applied rates.Special safeguards <strong>and</strong> special productsVarious opti<strong>on</strong>s have been advanced by developing countries, n<strong>on</strong>-governmentorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> others c<strong>on</strong>cerned about the implicati<strong>on</strong>s of import liberalisati<strong>on</strong> in<strong>agriculture</strong>. These opti<strong>on</strong>s include the applicati<strong>on</strong> of special products <strong>and</strong> differentialtreatment for 'special products'. The aim is to reverse the erosi<strong>on</strong> of special <strong>and</strong>differential treatment, <strong>and</strong> to address a broader set of c<strong>on</strong>cerns about food security.Special safeguards Under Article XIX of the GATT, safeguards can be introduced asa temporary measure, following cuts in tariffs in resp<strong>on</strong>se to import surges.Importantly, tariff reducti<strong>on</strong>s can <strong>on</strong>ly be reversed if it can be established that importscause, or threaten to cause, injury to domestic producers. Provisi<strong>on</strong>s under the 'sunset'clause restrict the use of a safeguard to four years. As an instrument for protecting <strong>and</strong>advancing food security in developing countries, the safeguard arrangements sufferfrom a number of <strong>problems</strong>. These relate to capacity, notably with regard toestablishing serious injury, cost of litigati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> time-horiz<strong>on</strong>. Recourse to ArticleXIX is feasible for commercial agribusiness interests (domestic <strong>and</strong> foreign-owned),operating in developing countries. But it is of limited use as a support mechanism forpublic policies <strong>on</strong> food security.19


The issues raised in the debate <strong>on</strong> special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment are offundamental importance for rural development policies, poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> foodsecurity. Unfortunately, the debate itself has been driven by a perverse logic. This isan area in multilateral obligati<strong>on</strong>s should be tailored to nati<strong>on</strong>al poverty-reducti<strong>on</strong>plans. Instead, <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> over <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> rules, driven by the c<strong>on</strong>cerns of industrialcountries to exp<strong>and</strong> market access, are defining what is possible in nati<strong>on</strong>al povertyplanning.Internati<strong>on</strong>al trade rules are <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e factor affecting food security outcomes <strong>and</strong> theinteracti<strong>on</strong> between the two is complex. Food security is not the same as food selfsufficiency– as witnessed by the prevalence of malnutriti<strong>on</strong> in India <strong>and</strong> Brazil.However, nati<strong>on</strong>al self-sufficiency can be an important factor, especially in lowincomecountries. At a household level, food security is related to the ability tocomm<strong>and</strong> access to nutriti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> a sustainable basis, either through producti<strong>on</strong> orexchange. Agricultural protecti<strong>on</strong> is not inherently good for food security, either at anati<strong>on</strong>al or at a household level; as in the EU <strong>and</strong> the US, the benefits can be capturedby the wealthy at the expense of the poor. By the same token, open markets <strong>and</strong>import liberalisati<strong>on</strong> can undermine food security, as witnessed by the experience of alarge number of countries.The important point here is that there is no trade-policy blueprint for advancing foodsecurity interests. Dem<strong>and</strong>s tabled by industrialised countries may cite a food securityrati<strong>on</strong>ale, but this is invariably a smokescreen for advancing the interests ofcommercial agricultural exporters. C<strong>on</strong>sider the rati<strong>on</strong>ale advanced by the US <strong>and</strong> theWorld Bank for greater differentiati<strong>on</strong> between developing countries. Headlinedistincti<strong>on</strong>s between, say, India <strong>and</strong> Brazil <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>e side <strong>and</strong> Burkina Faso <strong>on</strong> theother, have an intuitive appeal. India is a large country, <strong>and</strong> Brazil is the world’sfourth largest agricultural exporter. Viewed from a food security perspective, thedistincti<strong>on</strong>s appear less well grounded. According to the World Bank, around 16milli<strong>on</strong> Brazilians are affected by malnutriti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> there is a high incidence ofpoverty am<strong>on</strong>g smallholder farmers producing basic grains <strong>and</strong> other food crops. Inthe case of India, market size is not an antidote for rural poverty. More than threequartersof India’s poor – some 200 milli<strong>on</strong> people – live in rural areas, many ofwhich do not figure in the ‘shining India’ growth model.If <strong>on</strong>e of the aims of special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment in <strong>agriculture</strong> is to create anati<strong>on</strong>al policy space to address food security <strong>problems</strong>, the rati<strong>on</strong>ale for excludingIndia <strong>and</strong> Brazil is not obvious. The same applies to China. After all, the food security<strong>problems</strong> facing the north-east of Brazil, the 'poverty belt' in northern India, <strong>and</strong> theinterior of China are not diminished by export success.Developing countries have resp<strong>on</strong>ded to US <strong>and</strong> EU dem<strong>and</strong>s with an essentiallydefensive strategy focused <strong>on</strong> safeguards <strong>and</strong> special products. There are <strong>problems</strong>with this approach. The special safeguard is an instruments geared towards dealingwith import surges, not with a sustained <strong>and</strong> regular increase in imports. Bound tariffsystems lack the flexibility to resp<strong>on</strong>d to surges caused by large <strong>and</strong> unpredictablefluctuati<strong>on</strong>s in exchange rates, the gyrati<strong>on</strong>s in global market prices linked tochanging supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> patterns in major markets, <strong>and</strong>, of course, northernsubsidies. However, for countries seeking the policy space to reverse l<strong>on</strong>g-run,structural losses of food self-reliance in the interests of food security, rural21


development, <strong>and</strong> poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>, the problem goes bey<strong>on</strong>d anti-surge mechanisms.While protecti<strong>on</strong> is manifestly not a guaranteed route to food security, let al<strong>on</strong>e anindicator of policies that support the rural poor, there may be str<strong>on</strong>g infant industry<strong>and</strong> wider grounds for border protecti<strong>on</strong> to create incentives for local producti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong>investment.Some commentators argue that a special product provisi<strong>on</strong> could provide a frameworkfor addressing this problem. The argument is that products with a direct bearing <strong>on</strong>food security would be accorded a different status. However, this approach is notwithout <strong>problems</strong>. There is an immediately obvious sense in which, say, Cambodianrice or Ghanaian cassava might be c<strong>on</strong>strued as food security crops, meriting differenttreatment. But as the Government of India has pointed out, palm oil, rubber, <strong>and</strong>cott<strong>on</strong> are also food security crops. Markets for these crops play a pivotal role in thelives of milli<strong>on</strong>s of small farmers <strong>and</strong> rural labourers. In most developing countries,the poor are involved in the producti<strong>on</strong> a wide range of crops <strong>and</strong> a combinati<strong>on</strong> of<strong>on</strong>-farm <strong>and</strong> off-farm employment. Simplistic distincti<strong>on</strong>s between 'subsistence foodcrops' <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>e side <strong>and</strong> 'cash crops' <strong>on</strong> the other do not help. As is now widelyrecognised, successful rural development <strong>and</strong> poverty-reducti<strong>on</strong> strategies have tostart out by developing policy frameworks that reflect the realities of theselivelihoods.The danger is that a compartmentalised, special-product negotiating strategy at the<str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> will leave a large gap between the behind-the-border dictates of multilateralrules <strong>and</strong> the policy requirements for rural development. Developing countries facethe prospect of being locked into a negotiating framework under which they have towring c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s product-by-product in <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> with the EU <strong>and</strong> the US. Theoutcome is unlikely to be favourable.This is especially true from the perspective of the rural poor. Trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>inevitably involve trade-offs <strong>and</strong> hard bargains. The terms <strong>on</strong> which these bargains arestruck are shaped partly by power relati<strong>on</strong>s at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g>, <strong>and</strong> partly by power relati<strong>on</strong>sat a nati<strong>on</strong>al level. Take the case of Brazil – relevant because it is a G20 leader. In<strong>agriculture</strong>, the emphasis of Brazilian trade policy is <strong>on</strong> exp<strong>and</strong>ing markets. Some ofthe country's most powerful political lobbies – in sugar, fruit, <strong>and</strong> soybeans – areactive in shaping this policy through the trade ministry <strong>and</strong> the ministry dealing withcommercial <strong>agriculture</strong>. Smallholder farmers <strong>and</strong> agricultural labourers vulnerable toimport competiti<strong>on</strong> have a far weaker voice in influencing trade policy. So, too, doesthe ministry dealing with the n<strong>on</strong>-commercial sector. The danger is that any trade-offat the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> will reflect the priorities of powerful commercial interests, <strong>and</strong> not moremarginalised groups.Brazil is not an isolated case. It cannot be assumed that negotiators at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> havein the forefr<strong>on</strong>t of their minds the interests of the rural poor, especially when (as isoften the case) the governments they represent have a weak record in prioritising ruralpoverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. There are no simple answers. However, the limited publicawareness of what is being negotiated at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> inevitably diminishes the impact ofvoice of the poor, underlining the case for a greater emphasis <strong>on</strong> public disclosure <strong>and</strong>accountability at a nati<strong>on</strong>al level.5. Paths <strong>ahead</strong> for developing countries22


The outcome of the agricultural trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> – <strong>and</strong>, by extensi<strong>on</strong>, of the DohaRound itself – remains in the balance. Almost any scenario is plausible. Currentimprovements in the negotiating climate could lead to an early framework, followedby rapid progress towards full agreement. Alternatively, we could be operating in aperiod of post-Cancun complacency <strong>and</strong> heading either for a 'l<strong>on</strong>g haul' in the style ofthe Uruguay Round, or the collapse of <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>. One thing can be predicted withsome certainty, however: in the absence of sustained pressure from developingcountries, a <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> agreement will fail to address the <strong>problems</strong> caused by Northernagricultural policies.EU–US rapprochement thwartedSome notable successes have already been registered by the G20. In the run-up to theCancun summit, EU–US agricultural trade relati<strong>on</strong>s followed the Uruguay Roundtrajectory. Several m<strong>on</strong>ths of trans-Atlantic sabre-rattling gave way in August 2003 toa joint proposal reflecting a Blair House-style bilateral accommodati<strong>on</strong> of interest. Itis worth recalling some of the central features.Domestic support The Green Box would have been left intact, <strong>and</strong> the Blue Boxsubject to weak disciplines. Most US payments would have been exempt fromreducti<strong>on</strong> commitments, including those identified by the cott<strong>on</strong> dispute panel as tradedistorting. Blue Box provisi<strong>on</strong>s would have shielded the EU from adjustment, <strong>and</strong> –in <strong>on</strong>e interpretati<strong>on</strong> – given the US scope to remove counter-cyclical <strong>and</strong> otherpayments from any reducti<strong>on</strong> commitments.Export subsidies The language in this area was spectacularly weak. Export subsidies<strong>on</strong> ‘products of special interest to developing countries’ would be phased out over anundefined period, while others would be reduced.Market access The joint proposal combined the Uruguay Round <strong>and</strong> the Swissformula for a number of ‘import sensitive’ products, leaving large loopholes by settingaverage reducti<strong>on</strong> ranges, with (lower) minimum cuts.Special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment The most notable aspect of the EU–US proposalwas an attempt to rewrite the rules of special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment. It made afundamental distincti<strong>on</strong> between ‘significant net food exporting’ countries, whowould be eligible <strong>on</strong>ly for 'adjusted' c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> least-developed countries. Eventhe provisi<strong>on</strong>s of the Harbins<strong>on</strong> text <strong>on</strong> special products were excluded. Whilementi<strong>on</strong> was made of a special safeguard arrangement, this was applicable <strong>on</strong>ly to'import sensitive' tariff lines.Efforts to advance this agenda were derailed at Cancun, principally by the G20(though not without assistance from EU <strong>and</strong> US negotiators). In retrospect, it is clearthat the EU <strong>and</strong> the US underestimated both the resolve <strong>and</strong> the sophisticati<strong>on</strong> of theG20's negotiating strategy. Not <strong>on</strong>ly did that strategy include the development of analternative to the EU–US proposal – no mean feat for a coaliti<strong>on</strong> spanning major foodimporters <strong>and</strong> exporters – but it also encompassed a broader coaliti<strong>on</strong>-buildingexercise bey<strong>on</strong>d the G20. Particularly important in the latter c<strong>on</strong>text was a sustaineddialogue with the Africa Group <strong>and</strong> the least developed countries.23


African governments played a critical role at Cancun. Questi<strong>on</strong>s have been raisedabout the legality, in narrow <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> terms, of the dem<strong>and</strong>s tabled in the cott<strong>on</strong> initiativeby four West <strong>and</strong> Central African governments. However, the initiative articulated apowerful dem<strong>and</strong> for str<strong>on</strong>ger acti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> export subsidies, while at the same timeforcing the 'special products' approach <strong>on</strong> to the agenda. At a political level, both theproactive nature of the proposal <strong>and</strong> the refusal of the four countries to withdraw inthe face of c<strong>on</strong>siderable pressure from the US marked a c<strong>on</strong>siderable departure fromthe st<strong>and</strong>ard <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> negotiating script. It has to be added that the willingness of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> Director General to facilitate <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> the basis of the cott<strong>on</strong> initiativeframework was an important factor, not least in changing percepti<strong>on</strong>s of the role of thesecretariat.Some important less<strong>on</strong>s can be extrapolated from this background. Perhaps the mostimportant c<strong>on</strong>cerns the future of developing country coaliti<strong>on</strong>s. As <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> moveinto a more substantive phase, differences will inevitably emerge. African, ACP, <strong>and</strong>LDC governments remain deeply c<strong>on</strong>cerned over the threats posed by the erosi<strong>on</strong> oftariff <strong>and</strong> quota preferences. Many see the case brought by Brazil <strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong> againstEU sugar policy as a statement of hostile intent that will set a precedent. Several G20members – including Brazil <strong>and</strong> the Philippines – are in the Cairns Group of majorcommercial exporters. Other members – notably India – have viewed the dem<strong>and</strong>s ofthe Cairns Group in the area of import liberalisati<strong>on</strong> as a major threat. Both the EU<strong>and</strong> the US have highly developed divide <strong>and</strong> rule strategies that will seek to exploitthese tensi<strong>on</strong>s – witness the European Commissi<strong>on</strong>'s defence of the CAP sugar regimeby reference to the threat posed to ACP interests by trade liberalisati<strong>on</strong>.Ultimately, the strength <strong>and</strong> effectiveness of any coaliti<strong>on</strong> is determined not just byhow it articulates <strong>and</strong> promotes its shared interests, but also by how effectively it dealswith differences. Part of the challenge facing the G20 is to develop strategies forc<strong>on</strong>taining differences within the group, <strong>and</strong> for maintaining in good order the bridgesto other groups.Bey<strong>on</strong>d the Derbez textGovernments of the G20 <strong>and</strong> other developing countries are involved in a complexnegotiating process. Developments in <strong>agriculture</strong> will inevitably be affected bybargains struck in other areas – <strong>on</strong> the Singapore issues, for example. Moreover, <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> in <strong>agriculture</strong> cannot be viewed in isolati<strong>on</strong> from agricultural policyreform debates in the EU <strong>and</strong> the US. An incoming US administrati<strong>on</strong> will assess itsnegotiating space at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the light of how any agreement might affect the 2002Farm Act. In the EU, <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g> at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> are used by advocates of CAP reformto lever change, <strong>and</strong> opposed by CAP beneficiaries bent <strong>on</strong> maintaining the status quo.Developing countries need to assess carefully the interacti<strong>on</strong> between forces drivingdomestic agricultural policies <strong>and</strong> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> negotiating strategies of industrialisedcountries. Issues of time-horiz<strong>on</strong> also matter. The AoA of the Uruguay Round hasclearly c<strong>on</strong>strained what it is possible to achieve in the current <str<strong>on</strong>g>negotiati<strong>on</strong>s</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Bey<strong>on</strong>dany c<strong>on</strong>crete gains that developing countries might achieve in the Doha Round, it isimportant that any agreement exp<strong>and</strong>s rather than restricts potential gains in futurerounds. How might these principles be translated into practice? That questi<strong>on</strong> can best24


e addressed by reference to the four key areas that will ultimately make – or break –a deal in <strong>agriculture</strong>.Domestic supportThe most immediate aim here should be that of restricting the scope for support thatgenerates export surpluses. Deep cuts in Amber Box support <strong>on</strong> a product-specificbasis <strong>and</strong> early removal of the Blue Box should be immediate priorities, as proposedin the G20 proposals. Divisi<strong>on</strong>s between the EU <strong>and</strong> the US over the Blue Box createscope in this area for divide <strong>and</strong> rule in a different directi<strong>on</strong>.Turning to the Green Box, the G20 is now arguably in a far str<strong>on</strong>ger positi<strong>on</strong> than itwas before Cancun. The cott<strong>on</strong> dispute panel has effectively demolished the myth thatcurrent payments in this area are decoupled, opening the door to a fundamental reviewof existing disciplines.The Derbez text suffers from a number of weaknesses <strong>on</strong> domestic support. Blue Boxpayments would be capped <strong>and</strong> reduced under the Derbez proposals. Their eliminati<strong>on</strong>over, say, a five-year period would correct a major distorti<strong>on</strong>. Finally, the Derbez textsidesteps the questi<strong>on</strong> of how to tighten Green Box rules.Export subsidiesThis is an area in which the G20 has the potential to bank major gains. There are twolayers to the debate <strong>on</strong> export subsidies. The first c<strong>on</strong>cerns the (diminishing) use ofdirect export subsidies – now c<strong>on</strong>centrated in the EU sugar <strong>and</strong> dairy sectors – <strong>and</strong> theparallel use of export credits <strong>and</strong> food aid by the US. Achievable aims here include:an export-subsidy prohibiti<strong>on</strong> across all product groups within fiveyears;the eliminati<strong>on</strong> of the subsidy comp<strong>on</strong>ent of export-creditprogrammes in a similar time frame;a prohibiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the use of food aid for commercial marketdevelopment.Here too, there is scope for divide <strong>and</strong> rule. As a 'n<strong>on</strong>-subsidising' exporter, the USwill str<strong>on</strong>gly support moves to cut support, <strong>and</strong> for an obvious reas<strong>on</strong>: the burden ofadjustment will fall <strong>on</strong> the EU. For its part, the EU insists that any acti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> exportsubsidies is c<strong>on</strong>tingent <strong>on</strong> improved disciplines <strong>on</strong> US export credits <strong>and</strong> food aid.The Derbez text suffers from acute vagueness <strong>on</strong> export subsidies. It adopts the EU'slanguage in calling for the eliminati<strong>on</strong> of subsidies <strong>on</strong> products of interest todeveloping countries, but sets no date for the phasing out of other subsidies. Thelanguage also appears to point towards weak disciplines <strong>on</strong> export credits, focusing <strong>on</strong>a limit to repayment times. On food aid, the Derbez text merely recites the l<strong>on</strong>gestablishedprinciple that it should not be used to displace commercial activity.25


The sec<strong>on</strong>d layer of the export subsidy debate is more challenging. Both the cott<strong>on</strong><strong>and</strong> sugar disputes have highlighted the role of direct payments, c<strong>on</strong>sumer transfers<strong>and</strong> other arrangements in cross-subsidising exports. As shown earlier, <strong>on</strong>e of the<strong>problems</strong> with the current AoA framework is that many subsidies which lower theexport price of commodities are not treated as export subsidies. What is needed is anew measure of support to capture this effect – perhaps an OECD Export SupportEstimate. Once again, the dispute-panel process has strengthened the h<strong>and</strong> of the G20in terms of the range of feasible dem<strong>and</strong>s in this area.Market accessThis issue is comprehensively dealt with in another background paper. Here, werestrict ourselves to two strategic questi<strong>on</strong>s raised by tariff-cutting formulae <strong>and</strong>preferences. The current G20 approach is to argue for (i) a strict applicati<strong>on</strong> of theSwiss formula applied by tariff line, to address the twin <strong>problems</strong> of tariff peaks <strong>and</strong>tariff escalati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> (ii) the expansi<strong>on</strong> of tariff-rate quotas. From a negotiatingperspective, this raises a dilemma. If the G20 succeeds, presumably with US supportin getting a str<strong>on</strong>g commitment to a Swiss formula, the danger is that at least some ofits members will come under pressure to apply the same formula. It is certainlydifficult to envisage either the EU or the US c<strong>on</strong>ceding the applicati<strong>on</strong> of a Swissformula for themselves without reciprocal measures <strong>on</strong> the part of a large group ofdeveloping countries.Turning to the thorny issue of preferences, the challenge for the G20 is to avoidunnecessary divisi<strong>on</strong>. Some preference erosi<strong>on</strong> is inevitable, whatever the terms of afinal agreement: as MFN rates come down, preferences margins will fall. However,c<strong>on</strong>flict can be avoided if major exporters forego the right to challenge preferentialaccess in key areas, notably EU sugar. Such an approach clearly entails financial costsfor commercial exporters in the G20, but the political benefits of avoiding divisi<strong>on</strong>swith least-developed countries <strong>and</strong> the Africa group outweigh the costs.Special <strong>and</strong> differential treatmentThe most pressing c<strong>on</strong>cerns in this area revolve around market access <strong>and</strong>differentiati<strong>on</strong>.Applicati<strong>on</strong> of the Swiss formula would create unacceptable adjustment costs. Whiledeveloping countries may have an interest in proposing this approach forindustrialised countries, their own interest is in achieving a weak variant of theUruguay Round formula for themselves. Many developing country governments mayhave the flexibility to lower tariffs without fundamentally shifting relative prices,eroding self-reliance, or damaging rural livelihoods. But liberalisati<strong>on</strong> in this areashould reflect nati<strong>on</strong>al policy choices, not <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> imperatives.Food security is <strong>on</strong>e area in which a <strong>on</strong>e-size-fits-all model is doomed to failure.Distincti<strong>on</strong>s based <strong>on</strong> country size, export status, average income, dependence <strong>on</strong> foodimports, <strong>and</strong> so <strong>on</strong> may be of relevance in many areas, but they are at best weak <strong>and</strong> atworst irrelevant proxies for food security status.26


Developing countries could make a far more powerful case for a <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> regime thatallows for flexibility in this area. Far more should be d<strong>on</strong>e to highlight the potentialthreats posed by inappropriate forms of liberalisati<strong>on</strong>. Northern governmentsthemselves face an issue of credibility. It is <strong>on</strong>e thing to advocate open markets inareas where they have some claim to lead by example. It makes less sense to erode theright of poor countries to protect their producers when the EU <strong>and</strong> the US remain thesuperpowers of the subsidising world. Diluting special <strong>and</strong> differential treatment inthis c<strong>on</strong>text will inevitably be seen as another case of hypocrisy <strong>and</strong> double st<strong>and</strong>ards– <strong>and</strong> a case that will erode the legitimacy of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>WTO</str<strong>on</strong>g> itself in the eyes of many in thedeveloping world.C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>The Doha Round provides an opportunity to address l<strong>on</strong>g-st<strong>and</strong>ing inequalities inagricultural trade. Bringing Northern agricultural support systems under moreeffective multilateral rules could create new opportunities for poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. Itwould also strengthen the legitimacy <strong>and</strong> credibility of the rules-based multilateralsystem.It goes without saying that major obstacles remain. The negotiating power ofindividual developing countries is limited – <strong>and</strong> the vested interests affected by reformin industrialised countries are powerful. C<strong>on</strong>solidating <strong>and</strong> deepening the G20 <strong>and</strong> itsalliances with other groups holds the key to progress. While it is impossible todisassemble the AoA framework, in the short- to medium-term there is a str<strong>on</strong>g casefor focusing political energies <strong>on</strong> a number of discrete goals. These include aprohibiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> direct export subsidisati<strong>on</strong>, a revisi<strong>on</strong> of the distincti<strong>on</strong> between'distorting' <strong>and</strong> 'n<strong>on</strong>-distorting' subsidies, <strong>and</strong> measures to restrict exports of allproducts at prices below the costs of producti<strong>on</strong>.27

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!