11.07.2015 Views

Competition and Regulation in the Telecommunications Industry in ...

Competition and Regulation in the Telecommunications Industry in ...

Competition and Regulation in the Telecommunications Industry in ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>Telecommunications</strong> <strong>Industry</strong> <strong>in</strong>South AfricaPrepared for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Competition</strong> Commission byJames Hodge & Nicolas TheopoldSchool of Economics, University of Cape TownMarch 2001


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>4.3.3 Contestability...................................................................................................................................... 434.4 MOBILE....................................................................................................................................................... 454.4.1 Relevant Market.................................................................................................................................. 454.4.2 Market structure ................................................................................................................................. 454.4.3 Contestability...................................................................................................................................... 454.5 VALUE-ADDED NETWORK SERVICES (VANS) ............................................................................................ 474.5.1 Relevant markets ................................................................................................................................ 474.5.2 Market structure ................................................................................................................................. 474.5.3 Contestability...................................................................................................................................... 484.6 OTHER MOBILE SERVICES........................................................................................................................... 484.6.1 Relevant Markets................................................................................................................................ 484.6.2 Market Structure................................................................................................................................. 484.6.3 Contestability...................................................................................................................................... 495. REGULATORY ISSUES FOR THE SA TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY AND THEIRPOTENTIAL EFFICIENCY/PUBLIC INTEREST IMPACT....................................................................... 505.1 STRUCTURE................................................................................................................................................. 505.1.1 Vertical separation of networks.......................................................................................................... 515.1.2 Vertical separation of services from networks ................................................................................... 525.1.3 Horizontal separation of mobile services ........................................................................................... 525.2 ENTRY......................................................................................................................................................... 535.2.1 To Restrict Entry or Not ..................................................................................................................... 535.2.2 Deal<strong>in</strong>g with Entry Deterrence........................................................................................................... 555.2.3 To Actively Assist Entry or Not........................................................................................................... 555.2.4 Asymmetric regulation........................................................................................................................ 565.3 PRICING....................................................................................................................................................... 565.3.1 F<strong>in</strong>al consumer prices ........................................................................................................................ 565.3.2 Interconnection (Access) pric<strong>in</strong>g........................................................................................................ 575.4 QUALITY ..................................................................................................................................................... 58CONCLUDING REMARKS.............................................................................................................................. 59BIBLIOGRAPHY ............................................................................................................................................... 60ii


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>List of TablesTable 1.1: A breakdown of <strong>the</strong> telecommunications market _________________________________________ 2Table 1.2: Cost characteristics of local access technologies for telecommunications _____________________ 6Table 1.3: Direct forward l<strong>in</strong>kages - Telecommnuications share of <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put costs for sectors of <strong>the</strong>economy (1997) – percentage of total <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put costs _____________________________________ 13Table 1.4: Structure of capital requirements for a fixed l<strong>in</strong>e network provider <strong>and</strong> an Internet service provider(2000) _________________________________________________________________________________ 13Table 1.5: Direct backward l<strong>in</strong>kages – <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> communications <strong>in</strong>dustry (1997) –percentage of total <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put costs ____________________________________________________ 14Table 2.1: State of European Deregulation (1998)_______________________________________________ 21Table 3.1: Rollout Targets for Telkom <strong>in</strong> terms of License_________________________________________ 30List of FiguresFigure 1.1: A telecommunications network _____________________________________________________ 4Figure 1.2: Household expenditure patterns (1995)______________________________________________ 15Figure 2.2: Path of Regulatory Intensity ______________________________________________________ 22Figure 3.1: Proposed path of deregulation_____________________________________________________ 31iii


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>1. The Nature of <strong>the</strong> telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustryThis first section explores <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry as a start<strong>in</strong>gpo<strong>in</strong>t for competitive analysis. It beg<strong>in</strong>s by determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g market separation bothvertically (supply cha<strong>in</strong>) <strong>and</strong> horizontally. This discussion <strong>in</strong>cludes a look attechnological convergence <strong>and</strong> who are <strong>the</strong> current <strong>and</strong> future players <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market.It <strong>the</strong>n explores <strong>the</strong> possible forms of trade <strong>in</strong> telecommunications <strong>and</strong> how thatmight impact <strong>the</strong> geographical scope of <strong>the</strong> market <strong>and</strong> contestability. Lastly, itexam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> role that telecommunications plays <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> broader economy. This may<strong>in</strong>form how to trade off efficiency <strong>and</strong> public <strong>in</strong>terest considerations.1.1 The telecommunications marketThe telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry concerns <strong>the</strong> provision of two-way, one-to-onecommunications of voice, data <strong>and</strong> video. It is dist<strong>in</strong>ct form <strong>the</strong> broadcast<strong>in</strong>g market,which is typically a one-way, one-to-many communications service. However,convergence means that <strong>in</strong>frastructures developed for ei<strong>the</strong>r market can be adaptedto provide <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r service. Given <strong>the</strong>se economies of scope, it is often preferable toprovide both services.For regulatory purposes it is important to underst<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> vertical stages of production<strong>and</strong> possible horizontal market divisions <strong>in</strong> telecommunications. Table 1.1 provides<strong>the</strong> commonly used breakdown for telecommunication, not<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong> dynamicnature of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry makes such def<strong>in</strong>itions valid at a po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> time only.Table 1.1: A breakdown of <strong>the</strong> telecommunications marketProduction Stage Description Sub-stages Horizontal divisionsProvision of Network Provision of switch<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> • customer premises • fixed vs. mobile<strong>in</strong>frastructuretransmissionequipment• PABX vs. phone<strong>in</strong>frastructure• Local access • Fixed vs. mobile• Bus<strong>in</strong>ess vs.residential• Voice/data vs.broadb<strong>and</strong> video• National LongDistance• International LongProvision of servicesProvision of additional<strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong>technical support tooperate service over<strong>in</strong>frastructureDistance• L<strong>in</strong>e lease agreement• Content• value-added<strong>in</strong>frastructure• Technical serviceprovision• Customermanagement (bill<strong>in</strong>g& customer support)• basic voice vs. VANSvs. broadcast• Fixed vs. mobile• national long distancevs. <strong>in</strong>ternational• Bus<strong>in</strong>ess vs.residential<strong>Telecommunications</strong> production can roughly be divided <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> provision of network<strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> provision of services on that <strong>in</strong>frastructure. Typically a publicmonopoly is vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>and</strong> so provides all parts of <strong>the</strong> production cha<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong>all horizontal markets. However, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> context of deregulation it is important to focuson <strong>the</strong> various stages of production <strong>and</strong> not what <strong>in</strong>dividual firms do. In this way it is2


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>easier to identify essential facilities <strong>and</strong> anti-competitive behaviour stemm<strong>in</strong>g fromvertical <strong>in</strong>tegration. It is also easier to track where competition can feasibly survivewithout regulation.1.1.1 Provision of Network InfrastructureNetwork providers operate <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure on which various telecommunicationservices are run. Networks are made up of switches <strong>and</strong> transmission. The switchesprovide <strong>the</strong> rout<strong>in</strong>g of voice, data, <strong>and</strong> video signals through <strong>the</strong> network. Thetransmission medium can be separated <strong>in</strong>to fixed l<strong>in</strong>e (twisted pair of copper wires,fibre optic, coaxial cable) or wireless (satellite, cellular radio, microwave, PCS).The big technological changes <strong>in</strong> network provision have been (Laffont & Tirole2000):• <strong>the</strong> rapidly decreas<strong>in</strong>g costs of switches <strong>and</strong> transmission equipment• <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g capacity <strong>and</strong> speed of transmission mediums – both <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>transmission material (e.g. fibre optic) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> improved compression of signals(e.g. ADSL or asymmetric digital subscriber l<strong>in</strong>es which <strong>in</strong>crease speeds oncopper paired wire)• <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>telligence of <strong>the</strong> networks enabl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m to improve <strong>the</strong>irefficiency <strong>and</strong> beg<strong>in</strong> to offer a wide variety of services beyond mere telephony(discussed below)• <strong>the</strong> convergence of different <strong>in</strong>dustries due to <strong>the</strong> common use of digital format.The <strong>in</strong>dustries relate to <strong>the</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>al purpose for which <strong>the</strong> networks were built –telecommunications (voice), broadcast<strong>in</strong>g (video) <strong>and</strong> comput<strong>in</strong>g (data)There are three different components to <strong>the</strong> network that can be seen as threedifferent stages of production. These are local access, long-distance <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational. Figure 1.1 below demonstrates how <strong>the</strong>se three components<strong>in</strong>terconnect to form a complete <strong>in</strong>ternational telecommunications network. It looks ata mixed fixed l<strong>in</strong>e/mobile example. The local access network connects <strong>the</strong> customerpremises to <strong>the</strong> local switch through <strong>the</strong> local loop. From <strong>the</strong> local switch <strong>the</strong>re is an<strong>in</strong>teroffice transmission facility to ei<strong>the</strong>r o<strong>the</strong>r local switches or long-distance (nationalor <strong>in</strong>ternational) po<strong>in</strong>ts-of-presence. The long-distance networks <strong>the</strong>n transmit <strong>the</strong>signal to ano<strong>the</strong>r long-distance po<strong>in</strong>t-of-presence where it is distributed to a localswitch <strong>and</strong> onto <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r customer premises. What follows is a more detaileddiscussion of each component of <strong>the</strong> supply cha<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> various technologicalplatforms used.3


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Figure 1.1: A telecommunications networkCustomer premisesCustomer premisesFIXED LINELocalLoopLocalSwitchLocalSwitchLongdistancePoPCustomer h<strong>and</strong>setCustomer h<strong>and</strong>setBaseStationBaseStationMOBILELocalSwitchLongdistancePoPCustomer premises equipment (CPE)The concern here is <strong>the</strong> retail supply of customer premises equipment <strong>and</strong> not <strong>the</strong>manufacture of <strong>the</strong> items. CPEs <strong>in</strong>clude fixed l<strong>in</strong>e telephones, mobile h<strong>and</strong>sets, <strong>and</strong>PABXs (private exchange equipment for bus<strong>in</strong>ess use). Each of <strong>the</strong>se can beconsidered a separate market. In <strong>the</strong> heyday of public monopoly, <strong>the</strong> customerpremises equipment had to be supplied by <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent PSTN. This monopolyposition, on what is essentially a service with no natural monopoly features,represented an opportunity for abnormal profits to be made. Almost without fail <strong>the</strong>first step <strong>in</strong> any deregulation process is to liberalise this part of <strong>the</strong> supply cha<strong>in</strong>.Local AccessLocal access can now be provided by a number of different technologies, each withdifferent cost structure <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore different degrees of substitutability with <strong>the</strong>traditional public switched telephone network (PSTN). The focus below will be onfixed l<strong>in</strong>e (PSTN, data networks, cable TV) vs. wireless (fixed or mobile) options.Although local access is be<strong>in</strong>g h<strong>and</strong>led as one stage of production, it should be notedthat this stage can be broken down fur<strong>the</strong>r. In particular,• connection of premises to local loop• local loop• local exchange (switch)In <strong>the</strong> search for greater competition at <strong>the</strong> local access level, it may be desirable tofur<strong>the</strong>r unbundle <strong>the</strong> production process <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d ways to <strong>in</strong>ject competition. For<strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>the</strong> SA White Paper on telecommunications suggests allow<strong>in</strong>g communitygroups <strong>and</strong> SMMEs putt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> local loops that <strong>the</strong>n connect to <strong>the</strong> Telkom PSTN. In<strong>the</strong> USA, Competitive Access Providers (CAPs) have emerged to connect largecustomers directly to <strong>the</strong> long distance networks po<strong>in</strong>ts-of-presence (PoPs),4


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>effectively bypass<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> PSTN (<strong>the</strong>se access l<strong>in</strong>es are po<strong>in</strong>t-to-po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>and</strong> have noswitch<strong>in</strong>g capacity) (Laffont & Tirole 2000).Fixed L<strong>in</strong>eWith<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> group of network providers that use fixed l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>frastructure, networks werehistorically built to focus on one of three different types of transmission – voice, dataor image. However, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly networks are offer<strong>in</strong>g all three. This is feasiblebecause almost all networks now use a digital format.In voice, <strong>the</strong> traditional PSTN consists ma<strong>in</strong>ly of copper or coaxial cable transmissionequipment at <strong>the</strong> local access level <strong>and</strong> switch<strong>in</strong>g equipment that allows two-waytransmission between two <strong>in</strong>dividual po<strong>in</strong>ts on <strong>the</strong> network by establish<strong>in</strong>g adedicated l<strong>in</strong>e between two po<strong>in</strong>ts for <strong>the</strong> duration of a call. The transmissionmediums have low capacity or network speed (measured <strong>in</strong> bits per second) mak<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong>m <strong>in</strong>adequate for video transmission <strong>and</strong> a slow but adequate medium for datatransmission. However, recent technological developments <strong>in</strong> data compression havesubstantially <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>the</strong> speeds available on <strong>the</strong>se wires (<strong>in</strong> particular <strong>the</strong>asymmetrical digital subscriber l<strong>in</strong>e systems – ADSL – <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r DSL technologies).Upgrad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> networks to provide greater speed does require additional <strong>in</strong>vestments<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> local access <strong>in</strong>frastructure. An alternative is <strong>the</strong> use of fibre optic, which has afar greater network capacity. Due to <strong>the</strong> higher cost of fibre optic, it is only costeffective with large bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>and</strong> not residential homes <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> local accesscomponent of <strong>the</strong> network. It is used extensively <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> long-distance <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational networks. Ei<strong>the</strong>r way, it is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly possible for PSTN networks to beupgraded to offer video services too. In fact, grow<strong>in</strong>g use of capacity for datatransmission (i.e. <strong>the</strong> Internet <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>tra-corporate transfers) make <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong>fibre optic or ADSL <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly worthwhile, offer<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> spr<strong>in</strong>gboard to broadcast<strong>in</strong>g.Cable TV (CATV) networks (video networks) use a coaxial cable with broadcastquality network speeds as <strong>the</strong>ir transmission medium. Initially <strong>the</strong>se networks wereonly focused on broadcast <strong>and</strong> so were established with one-way, one-to-manytransmission (tree-<strong>and</strong>-branch structure), disqualify<strong>in</strong>g one-to-one communication.However, where cable operators have entered telephony, <strong>the</strong>y have upgraded <strong>the</strong>irnetworks to h<strong>and</strong>le two-way transmission. This has enabled <strong>the</strong> creation of <strong>the</strong> new‘pay-per-view’ television services, <strong>and</strong> also allowed <strong>the</strong>m to actively enter <strong>the</strong> Internetproviders <strong>and</strong> telephony market.Dedicated data networks may be private or public (Internet). Data can be run overany network <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> fact, most local access to dedicated data networks occursthrough ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> PSTN, <strong>the</strong> cable TV network or a mobile service. As such, <strong>the</strong>discussion of data networks is largely a long-distance issue. However, largerbus<strong>in</strong>esses are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly be<strong>in</strong>g connected directly to <strong>the</strong>se long-distance datanetworks mak<strong>in</strong>g it worth a mention here. The switch<strong>in</strong>g equipment of data networksdoes not establish a dedicated l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stead routes ‘packets’ of data on commonusage l<strong>in</strong>es from one po<strong>in</strong>t to ano<strong>the</strong>r through <strong>the</strong> path of least resistance. This isefficient for data but as l<strong>in</strong>e traffic congestion can delay packets, this has previouslybeen unsuitable for quality voice or image transmission. However, recentInternational <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Union (ITU) agreements on a common gatewayprotocol for pass<strong>in</strong>g multimedia from telephone networks to data networks shouldgreatly improve <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> near future (ITU 1999). This will see priority be<strong>in</strong>ggiven to voice <strong>and</strong> image packets, avoid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> problem of congestion.5


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Table 1.2 exam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> cost structure of different network types. As it reveals, <strong>the</strong>cost structure <strong>in</strong> fixed l<strong>in</strong>e networks (PSTN or cable) is geared towards sunk <strong>and</strong>fixed costs mak<strong>in</strong>g it largely <strong>in</strong>sensitive to traffic volumes. For this reason it is oftennoted that <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al cost of mak<strong>in</strong>g a phone call is negligible. In fact, <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>alcost/revenue decision for <strong>the</strong> PSTN operator is whe<strong>the</strong>r to connect a new customeror not (Laffont & Tirole 2000). If <strong>the</strong> new customer is expected to generate morerevenue than it costs to <strong>in</strong>stall <strong>the</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> PSTN will <strong>in</strong>stall <strong>the</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e. The resultof this cost structure is that economies of scale <strong>and</strong> density are reasonably large <strong>and</strong><strong>the</strong>re is a large <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>vestment required to beg<strong>in</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g local access.The sunk costs are largely <strong>the</strong> trenches <strong>and</strong> ducts for wire that can make up to 40%of annualised costs (Caves 1995). Allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> distribution through poles aboveground does lower costs. These sunk costs are <strong>the</strong> reason that lower cost entrantsare companies with a local transmission network already <strong>in</strong> place – e.g. cable TVcompanies or electricity companies. In <strong>the</strong>se cases <strong>the</strong>re are economies of scope asmany of <strong>the</strong> additional costs of roll<strong>in</strong>g out a network are already <strong>in</strong>curred. Thedifficulty of course is allocat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se costs between <strong>the</strong> different services. The o<strong>the</strong>rservice that cable can enter once upgraded for telephony is data transmission.Cave (1995) notes that <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> comparison of costs between cable <strong>and</strong> PSTN, <strong>the</strong>follow<strong>in</strong>g conclusions may be drawn:• Cost per home passed (<strong>the</strong> local loop) is higher for a CATV network• The <strong>in</strong>cremental cost of provision of a telecommunications service by a CATVoperator with an established local loop is a small fraction of <strong>the</strong> total cost faced bya PSTN• For <strong>the</strong> subscriber already connected to <strong>the</strong> CATV local loop <strong>the</strong> cost disparitywith a telecommunications provider is even greater.Table 1.2 assumes that <strong>the</strong> cable provider already has a local loop <strong>in</strong> existence <strong>and</strong>is provid<strong>in</strong>g both video <strong>and</strong> telephony (hence exploit<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir economies of scope).The conclusion one can draw is that cable can <strong>in</strong> all likelihood be considered <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>same market for telecommunications once established.Table 1.2: Cost characteristics of local access technologies for telecommunicationsFixed l<strong>in</strong>e CATV network Fixed wireless Mobile wirelessFixed/variable ratio High Medium Low LowSunk/salvageableratioTrafficsensitive/non-trafficsensitiveHigh Medium* Low LowLow Medium* High HighEconomies of scale Medium Medium Small SmallEconomies ofdensityLarge Large Small SmallEconomies of scope Possible Yes No PossibleInitial <strong>in</strong>vestmentrequiredRequires specialh<strong>and</strong>setLarge Medium Small SmallNo No No Yes*Based on some economies of scope by offer<strong>in</strong>g video <strong>and</strong> telephony services6


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Reproduced from Cave (1995)If <strong>the</strong> PSTN were to exploit <strong>the</strong>ir potential economies of scope <strong>in</strong>to video <strong>the</strong>n part of<strong>the</strong> sunk costs allocated to telephony would be shared with o<strong>the</strong>r services. ThePSTN has already lowered some of <strong>the</strong> costs by exploit<strong>in</strong>g its ability to provideaccess to two-way transmission data networks (i.e. Internet or private data networks).The exponential growth <strong>in</strong> traffic volume has been associated with data <strong>and</strong> notvoice. This enables PSTNs to operate at greater levels of capacity utilisation <strong>and</strong> solower <strong>the</strong> unit costs. This is a strong reason for <strong>the</strong> better productivity performance ofUS telephone companies.Wireless NetworksWireless networks differ from fixed l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir use of <strong>the</strong> radio frequency spectrumfor transmission. The local access process <strong>in</strong>volves a h<strong>and</strong>set for <strong>the</strong> subscribertransmitt<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>and</strong> from a base station us<strong>in</strong>g a specific spectrum that <strong>the</strong> networkprovider is licensed to use. The base stations are usually connected to each o<strong>the</strong>r orano<strong>the</strong>r network through a fixed l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>frastructure.In local access <strong>the</strong>re are two types of wireless networks – fixed <strong>and</strong> mobile. The fixedwireless local loop is a recent addition <strong>and</strong> is be<strong>in</strong>g used to provide a ‘last drop’ to <strong>the</strong>consumer for fixed l<strong>in</strong>e voice or data networks. It is similar to two-way radio where<strong>the</strong> physical coverage is very limited, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> receiv<strong>in</strong>g device (a telephone) is oftenfixed <strong>in</strong> location. The same receiv<strong>in</strong>g device as fixed l<strong>in</strong>es is used. In terms of amarket boundary for competition analysis, it is not designed to compete with <strong>the</strong>cellular networks but ra<strong>the</strong>r to provide a cheap alternative to us<strong>in</strong>g fixed wire as <strong>the</strong>last drop to <strong>the</strong> home. Therefore it would usually fall <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> fixed telephony market(<strong>in</strong> fact it is usually rolled out by <strong>the</strong> PSTN as part of a mixed technology strategy –Telkom is no exception).The cellular networks provide local access but also <strong>the</strong> added advantage of mobility.The subscriber is required to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> a h<strong>and</strong>set that cannot be used for fixed l<strong>in</strong>e orfixed wireless access (a switch<strong>in</strong>g cost). The current mobile networks are constra<strong>in</strong>ed<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir network speed to offer<strong>in</strong>g voice <strong>and</strong> data services only. However, <strong>the</strong> socalled3 rd Generation or Universal Mobile <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Services (UMTS)hope to achieve networks speeds that would enable <strong>the</strong> transmission of video too.The first networks of this k<strong>in</strong>d are due to be operational <strong>in</strong> Japan <strong>in</strong> 2002.The cost structure of mobile is different to that of fixed l<strong>in</strong>es (see table 1.2). Thespac<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> base stations (<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> number required) is dependent on <strong>the</strong>traffic volumes. The result is that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>vestment required to establish a localaccess <strong>in</strong>frastructure is lower than that of fixed l<strong>in</strong>es. It also means that <strong>the</strong>re arelower economies of scale <strong>and</strong> density, mak<strong>in</strong>g more network providers viable.A key question is <strong>the</strong> extent to which mobile competes with fixed l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> localaccess market (i.e. is a close enough substitute to be considered <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> samemarket). This is crucial for competition <strong>and</strong> regulatory analysis. From a use <strong>and</strong>quality of product perspective, <strong>the</strong>y clearly offer <strong>the</strong> same potential group of basic<strong>and</strong> advanced voice products but with mobile hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> added feature of mobility.What may <strong>the</strong>refore determ<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same product market is <strong>the</strong>difference <strong>in</strong> price between <strong>the</strong> two or whe<strong>the</strong>r o<strong>the</strong>r services are bundled <strong>in</strong> too (<strong>in</strong>particular data services). If voice is bundled with data services <strong>the</strong>n fixed l<strong>in</strong>ecurrently holds a broader array of products to mobile, where data is available but <strong>in</strong> afar more limited way due to screen size. The actual cost differential depends on <strong>the</strong>7


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>relative density of subscribers. Wireless is cheaper at lower densities due to <strong>the</strong> lowfixed costs, while fixed l<strong>in</strong>e is cheaper at higher densities. The cross-over po<strong>in</strong>t isestimated to be <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> range of 200-800 subscribers per km 2 from US <strong>and</strong> UK studies(Cave 1995). This makes mobile more expensive <strong>in</strong> urban <strong>and</strong> metropolitan areaswith high subscriber rates. However, <strong>in</strong> many develop<strong>in</strong>g countries with lowtelephony density of use, cellular is prov<strong>in</strong>g to be a good substitute for fixed l<strong>in</strong>e(South Africa may well be a case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t). Rapid technological developments <strong>in</strong>mobile communications could make it even more substitutable.Mobile telecommunications also <strong>in</strong>cludes satellite personal communications services.Satellite makes use of more powerful devices to transmit to one of a number of earthstations, which <strong>in</strong> turn l<strong>in</strong>k to each o<strong>the</strong>r via one or more satellites. The greaterdistances <strong>the</strong> receiv<strong>in</strong>g equipment must transmit over, means <strong>the</strong>y are larger <strong>and</strong>more expensive than cellular. However, <strong>the</strong> use of satellites enables <strong>the</strong> network tom<strong>in</strong>imise <strong>the</strong> number of earth-based transmission stations. This will not be discussedbecause a) <strong>the</strong> first global start-ups have all failed, <strong>and</strong> b) <strong>the</strong> cost is so much higherthan fixed l<strong>in</strong>e or mobile that it cannot be considered remotely <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same market.O<strong>the</strong>r wireless communications also <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> broadcast<strong>in</strong>g group (radio, free-to-airTV <strong>and</strong> Pay TV) which are one-to-many operations without two-way capacity <strong>and</strong> socannot offer telecommunications.F<strong>in</strong>ally, one can <strong>in</strong>clude two-way radio <strong>and</strong> radio trunk<strong>in</strong>g. Two-way radio is oftentransmitted over very short distances <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>cludes networks for emergency services<strong>and</strong> communication with<strong>in</strong> a def<strong>in</strong>ed corporate space. Often <strong>the</strong> distances are shortenough that no transmission stations are required, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> h<strong>and</strong>-held devices aresufficient. The longer distances are covered by radio trunk<strong>in</strong>g, which operate <strong>in</strong> afashion similar to cellular networks. Nei<strong>the</strong>r are suitable for public local accesstelecommunications <strong>and</strong> so will not be discussed fur<strong>the</strong>r.Long Distance (National <strong>and</strong> International)Local access networks connect to a long distance network through a po<strong>in</strong>t-ofpresence(PoP). The long-distance network is made up of <strong>the</strong>se PoP exchanges <strong>and</strong>a transmission network. Given that <strong>the</strong>se networks draw on a large pool of localaccess subscribers, <strong>the</strong>y are able to get greater density of use <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir transmissionnetworks. As a result, most long distance networks use fibre optic when us<strong>in</strong>g a fixedl<strong>in</strong>e solution. Alternative transmission mechanisms <strong>in</strong>clude satellite <strong>and</strong> microwave(national only). Despite <strong>the</strong> choice of technologies available, a s<strong>in</strong>gle market isdef<strong>in</strong>ed as one for national long-distance <strong>and</strong> for <strong>in</strong>ternational long distance. Inaddition, as most of <strong>the</strong>se networks have sufficient network speed for broadcastquality, <strong>the</strong>re is no real need to differentiate at <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure stage between voice,data <strong>and</strong> video.As with local access, <strong>the</strong>re are economies of scope <strong>in</strong> roll<strong>in</strong>g out fibre optic longdistancenetworks. A substantial proportion of <strong>the</strong> costs are <strong>in</strong> pay<strong>in</strong>g royalties tol<strong>and</strong>owners to pass <strong>the</strong> transmission cable through <strong>and</strong> putt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> place <strong>in</strong>frastructureto carry <strong>the</strong> transmission medium (Cave 1995). If a new entrant already has anational <strong>in</strong>frastructure (e.g. railways, electricity grid), <strong>the</strong>n some of <strong>the</strong>se costs will bespared allow<strong>in</strong>g a faster <strong>and</strong> cheaper rollout.8


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>1.1.2 Provision of ServicesThe network <strong>in</strong>frastructure is <strong>the</strong> basis on which services are provided. The<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>telligence of telecommunications networks has permitted a proliferationof services that are feasible beyond <strong>the</strong> basic local, national <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationaltelephony. The new telephony-related services <strong>in</strong>clude automatic callback,number/name identification, selective call rejection/acceptance, voice messag<strong>in</strong>g,selective rout<strong>in</strong>g of calls, text messag<strong>in</strong>g, fax, call<strong>in</strong>g card, etc. In addition, <strong>the</strong> rangeof data/video services has proliferated with <strong>the</strong> most common <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a full Internetoffer<strong>in</strong>g (email, world-wide-web), EDI (electronic data <strong>in</strong>terchange), pag<strong>in</strong>g, manageddata network services, video-conferenc<strong>in</strong>g, database access <strong>and</strong> transactions, videoon-dem<strong>and</strong>.Service provision can be split <strong>in</strong>to two basic components – value-added networkservices (VANS) <strong>and</strong> basic voice. From this po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>the</strong>re can be fur<strong>the</strong>r separation <strong>in</strong>towireless vs fixed l<strong>in</strong>e, local/long distance/<strong>in</strong>ternational, <strong>and</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess/residential.VANS are described as <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g electronic data <strong>in</strong>terchange, electronic mail,protocol conversion, database access, managed data network services, voice mail,store <strong>and</strong> forward fax, video conferenc<strong>in</strong>g, telecommunications related to publish<strong>in</strong>g<strong>and</strong> advertis<strong>in</strong>g services <strong>and</strong> electronic <strong>in</strong>formation services, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Internetservice provision.The provision of services occurs on top of <strong>the</strong> network <strong>in</strong>frastructure. Historically <strong>the</strong>network provider was also <strong>the</strong> provider of services. However, unbundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> servicefrom <strong>the</strong> network is feasible <strong>and</strong> has been <strong>the</strong> path of most deregulation processes.A service provider who does not own <strong>the</strong> network offers <strong>the</strong> service by ei<strong>the</strong>r leas<strong>in</strong>gpart of <strong>the</strong> network from <strong>the</strong> network provider <strong>and</strong> enhanc<strong>in</strong>g this with one or moreservice components, or <strong>in</strong>terconnect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir own network to o<strong>the</strong>rs <strong>in</strong> order toprovide <strong>the</strong> service. The service component is added for essentially two reasons – a)because <strong>the</strong> network provider does not offer <strong>the</strong> service (by regulation or choice), orb) <strong>the</strong> network provider is seen to be <strong>in</strong>efficient at that service <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> serviceprovider is able to offer it at lower cost or better quality.In terms of efficiency arguments, a number of possibilities emerge. It could be that anetwork provider is us<strong>in</strong>g dated or <strong>in</strong>efficient technology at po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> networkwhich a service provider may choose to replicate <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n lease or <strong>in</strong>terconnect too<strong>the</strong>r parts of <strong>the</strong> network to compete. This may be as simple as <strong>the</strong> credit <strong>and</strong> bill<strong>in</strong>gcomponent, or <strong>in</strong>ternet access via <strong>the</strong> local telephone network but us<strong>in</strong>g a nationaldata network. Alternatively, <strong>the</strong> large network provider may not be able to adequatelyprice discrim<strong>in</strong>ate amongst all niches <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market <strong>and</strong> a service provider may leaseexcess capacity <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> network for <strong>the</strong> purpose of niche resale. This is often <strong>the</strong> casewith <strong>in</strong>ternational or national telephony services providers. The <strong>in</strong>ternet providesano<strong>the</strong>r example of niche servic<strong>in</strong>g – an important component of what customersseek <strong>in</strong> service providers is member services such as home page news, l<strong>in</strong>ks <strong>and</strong>community <strong>in</strong>formation. These can be tailored to niche markets while <strong>the</strong> cost can bekept <strong>the</strong> same by leas<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>es.The additional components that service providers br<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> network are:• Service-specific <strong>in</strong>frastructure – this <strong>in</strong>cludes additions to <strong>the</strong> network<strong>in</strong>frastructure required to technically provide a particular advanced service. Forexample, <strong>in</strong> Internet services <strong>the</strong>se would <strong>in</strong>clude a national po<strong>in</strong>ts of presence(PoPs) network l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> long-distance data network (Internet backbone),9


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g to a server farm that would <strong>in</strong>clude a router, au<strong>the</strong>ntication server, firewall,mail hosts, proxy servers <strong>and</strong> local content servers.• Some form of customer management systems – this would <strong>in</strong>clude customer<strong>in</strong>formation, bill<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> customer support (call centre)• Content – some advanced services may have content that will be received by <strong>the</strong>customer (e.g. Internet, video-on-dem<strong>and</strong>)A local example of separation of network <strong>and</strong> service provider is <strong>the</strong> cellular <strong>in</strong>dustry<strong>in</strong> South Africa. The network providers do not retail to <strong>the</strong> public but <strong>in</strong>steadwholesale network access to a group of approved service providers. These providers<strong>in</strong> turn offer retail outlets to access customers, <strong>the</strong>y stock <strong>and</strong> sell <strong>the</strong> phones, do <strong>the</strong>credit checks, l<strong>in</strong>k <strong>the</strong> customer to <strong>the</strong> network <strong>and</strong> perform all bill<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> debtcollection.Horizontal market divisions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> service component can be taken from <strong>the</strong> divisions<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> network markets <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>clude:• Local vs long distance vs <strong>in</strong>ternational – st<strong>and</strong>ard voice products• Bus<strong>in</strong>ess vs residential – <strong>the</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess market has greater capacity usage <strong>and</strong>concentration chang<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>and</strong> product package provided.• Data vs. voice vs. video – separation of voice products from Internet <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rVANS from broadcast type products.• Fixed vs mobile – this would apply across all of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r divisions e.g. mobileInternet may be separated from fixed l<strong>in</strong>e by <strong>the</strong> more limited range ofapplications it supports (for now).A key question when exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> horizontal market divisions is product bundl<strong>in</strong>g<strong>and</strong> technological change. In terms of product bundl<strong>in</strong>g, most voice services offer <strong>the</strong>more advanced features as part of <strong>the</strong> service. Are <strong>the</strong>se additional products or are<strong>the</strong>y part of a basic voice service as most companies provide <strong>the</strong>m? In terms oftechnological change, it needs to be recognised that product boundaries willcont<strong>in</strong>ually change <strong>and</strong> so need to be reassessed periodically.1.1.3 Features of NetworksThe pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> competitive behaviour amongst network providers is <strong>in</strong>fluenced by anumber of factors peculiar to network <strong>in</strong>dustries. First, <strong>the</strong> value of a network isrelated to <strong>the</strong> number of customers connected to that network. Therefore, it is <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>terests of all competitors to <strong>in</strong>terconnect with each o<strong>the</strong>r to ga<strong>in</strong> access to as broada customer base as possible <strong>in</strong> order to enhance <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong>ir respectivenetworks. The ability to <strong>in</strong>terconnect also means that firms can compete with o<strong>the</strong>rnetwork providers on one part of <strong>the</strong>ir network without hav<strong>in</strong>g to duplicate <strong>the</strong> entirenetwork – for <strong>in</strong>stance, firms may compete on long distance telephony by build<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong>ir own long distance <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terconnect<strong>in</strong>g to a local network to reach<strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al customers. For service providers <strong>in</strong>terconnection is key. Although <strong>the</strong>regulation stipulates that <strong>in</strong>terconnection must occur, it is <strong>the</strong> terms of this<strong>in</strong>terconnection that determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> competitiveness of alternative<strong>in</strong>frastructures.10


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>1.2 Forms of <strong>in</strong>ternational tradeAccord<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> WTO negotiat<strong>in</strong>g rules, trade <strong>in</strong> telecommunications services canoccur through four possible modes of supply – cross-border supply, consumptionabroad, commercial presence <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> presence of natural persons. These will bediscussed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> context of network <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong> services.1.2.1 Provision of network <strong>in</strong>frastructureUntil recently, <strong>the</strong> most common form of trade between countries has been throughcross-border supply of <strong>in</strong>ternational network services. Trade occurs through <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>terconnection of networks <strong>in</strong> order to complete or route an <strong>in</strong>ternational call.Included <strong>in</strong> this trade is <strong>the</strong> third-party rout<strong>in</strong>g of calls (e.g. Zimbabwe may route<strong>in</strong>ternational calls via South Africa). Imports are considered to be outgo<strong>in</strong>g calls that<strong>the</strong> network provider <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r country charges to be completed. Incom<strong>in</strong>g calls orones third-party routed by a country’s network are considered exports. Cross-bordersupply is dom<strong>in</strong>ated by, but not limited to, <strong>in</strong>terconnection charges for data, voice orvideo. The extent to which trade offers competition depends on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>frastructure of ano<strong>the</strong>r country is able to service <strong>the</strong> South African market. This islikely with <strong>in</strong>ternational services as satellites have broad footpr<strong>in</strong>ts over wholeregions <strong>and</strong> fibre optic networks often loop past many countries. It is possible forsatellite communications to bypass all domestic <strong>in</strong>frastructure by pass<strong>in</strong>g signaldistribution through a earth gateway station located <strong>in</strong> ano<strong>the</strong>r country.With <strong>the</strong> grow<strong>in</strong>g liberalisation of communications services <strong>in</strong>ternationally, an<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly important form of trade has become commercial presence. In order toprovide communications services to consumers <strong>in</strong> a country beyond complet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir<strong>in</strong>ternational calls to ano<strong>the</strong>r country, network <strong>and</strong> service providers need to have aphysical presence <strong>in</strong> that country. All networks, with <strong>the</strong> exclusion of satellite, require<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> terrestrial transmission equipment <strong>and</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r physical l<strong>in</strong>es or radiofrequency. Even for satellite communication one still requires an earth station to l<strong>in</strong>kto <strong>the</strong> satellite, <strong>and</strong> authority for use of radio spectrum.Due to <strong>the</strong> grow<strong>in</strong>g importance of commercial presence as a means of service trade,<strong>the</strong> presence of natural persons also becomes important on <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>in</strong>tracorporatetransferees only. The high dem<strong>and</strong>s for human capital <strong>in</strong> production meanthat companies enter<strong>in</strong>g a market may require to br<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own technicalexpertise <strong>in</strong> order to build <strong>and</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir network or service. However, <strong>the</strong>re areno trade dem<strong>and</strong>s beyond <strong>in</strong>ter-corporate transferees.1.2.2 Provision of servicesThe <strong>in</strong>terconnection of networks globally means that many data <strong>and</strong> video servicescan be provided from ano<strong>the</strong>r country <strong>in</strong> a cross-border fashion. It is common to f<strong>in</strong>demail, e-commerce <strong>and</strong> web-host<strong>in</strong>g services for South Africans be<strong>in</strong>g supplied fromservers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> USA. There is no doubt that domestic e-tailers compete with foreignones.In terms of voice products, <strong>the</strong>re is competition between service providers to route<strong>in</strong>ternational calls through <strong>the</strong>ir networks. In particular, call<strong>in</strong>g cards <strong>and</strong> call-backservices are a means to capture consumption abroad. When a traveller makes use ofa national call<strong>in</strong>g card when mak<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>ternational call, <strong>the</strong> call is routed through<strong>the</strong> network back home <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> this way provides revenue <strong>and</strong> ‘imports’. Many11


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>callback services have sprung up <strong>in</strong> countries like <strong>the</strong> USA whereby a customer fromSouth Africa places a call ‘as if’ <strong>the</strong>y were <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> USA through <strong>the</strong> callback operatorcall<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m <strong>and</strong> connect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m to <strong>the</strong> number <strong>the</strong>y wanted to call. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong>mobile telephony one can arrange <strong>in</strong>ternational roam<strong>in</strong>g agreements for mobilephone users to capture <strong>the</strong>ir consumption. Any calls that <strong>the</strong>y make abroad will berouted back through <strong>the</strong> domestic network, allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> domestic mobile networkprovider to capture some of <strong>the</strong> charges on that call.However, for basic voice products <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> local access market, <strong>the</strong> competition mustcome from domestically situated firms. As such, provisions around foreign ownershiplimits will serve to restrict competition.1.3 Role <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> economyCommunications services play a key role <strong>in</strong> any economy – from be<strong>in</strong>g an important<strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put to bus<strong>in</strong>ess, an enabl<strong>in</strong>g medium for a range of content providers,a significant item <strong>in</strong> household expenditure, <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ally a source of dem<strong>and</strong> fornumerous manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> service <strong>in</strong>dustries. What follows is a discussion of <strong>the</strong>role <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> broader economy of communications services as a package of bothnetwork <strong>and</strong> service providers. This component is severely limited by <strong>the</strong> statisticaldata. This is particularly problematic <strong>in</strong> a dynamic <strong>in</strong>dustry as dated statistics tend tobe widely off <strong>the</strong> mark. With telecommunications statistics, it is likely that datedstatistics will underestimate <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy.1.3.1 Role as Intermediate InputThe role of communications as an <strong>in</strong>termediate to bus<strong>in</strong>ess can be seen to have 2dimensions – a) as a cost item required to operate a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, b) as a strategic <strong>and</strong>competitive tool.As a cost item, communications does not appear that significant for most parts of <strong>the</strong>South African economy judg<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong> statistics <strong>in</strong> table 1.3 below. It representsonly 0.1% of total costs <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>and</strong> m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, 0.4% <strong>in</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries<strong>and</strong> 4.4% <strong>in</strong> service <strong>in</strong>dustries. However, <strong>the</strong>se figures def<strong>in</strong>itely underestimate <strong>the</strong>cost importance of communications for two important reasons. First, <strong>the</strong> data networkcosts are accounted for under <strong>the</strong> section titled bus<strong>in</strong>ess services, along with o<strong>the</strong>rbus<strong>in</strong>ess service items. Second, <strong>the</strong> latest <strong>in</strong>put-output data available for SouthAfrica is 1997, which was based on <strong>the</strong> 1993 table which was based on <strong>the</strong> 1988table. In each case, a new <strong>in</strong>put-output table is created by adjust<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> old one withnew national accounts data.As a strategic competitive tool, communications are becom<strong>in</strong>g more <strong>and</strong> more vital tobus<strong>in</strong>esses globally. Increased globalisation has resulted <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> requirement tocommunicate <strong>and</strong> transmit vast amounts of data to suppliers, <strong>in</strong>dustry customers <strong>and</strong>affiliates <strong>in</strong>ternationally on a timely basis. The rise of electronic commerce, has nowestablished a need <strong>in</strong> many <strong>in</strong>dustries to use communications networks to deal with<strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>al dem<strong>and</strong> of <strong>the</strong> household consumer too. In both cases, <strong>the</strong> need is for highspeed, high quality communications services that are geared to <strong>the</strong> specific needs of<strong>the</strong> firm <strong>and</strong> which are available at a cost that does not make it prohibitive tocommunicate or put <strong>the</strong>m at a competitive disadvantage to firms <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries.What matters most for an economy is <strong>the</strong> availability of world-class communicationservices at a reasonably competitive price, even if <strong>the</strong>y are not <strong>the</strong> cheapest.12


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Table 1.3: Direct forward l<strong>in</strong>kages - Telecommnuications share of <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put costs forsectors of <strong>the</strong> economy (1997) – percentage of total <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put costsSector% of <strong>in</strong>termediatecostsPrimary 0.2Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g 0.4Natural resource<strong>in</strong>tensive0.3Labour <strong>in</strong>tensive 0.5Scale <strong>in</strong>tensive 0.3Knowledge <strong>in</strong>tensive 0.6O<strong>the</strong>r 0.7Services 4.4Producer services 7.2Consumer services 3.4Infrastructural services 0.7Community/socialservices11.8Source: Wefa SAM (1997)1.3.2 Dem<strong>and</strong> for Intermediate InputsGrowth of <strong>the</strong> communications <strong>in</strong>dustry has some important trickle-down effects forcerta<strong>in</strong> parts of <strong>the</strong> economy <strong>and</strong> results <strong>in</strong> output <strong>and</strong> employment creation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>sesectors. There are two sources of such dem<strong>and</strong> – <strong>in</strong>vestment dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> ongo<strong>in</strong>goperations dem<strong>and</strong>.Investment dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>cludes capital goods required by <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry to <strong>in</strong>crease itssize of operations. Table 1.4 shows <strong>the</strong> capital structure of <strong>the</strong> fixed l<strong>in</strong>e providerTelkom <strong>and</strong> an Internet service provider M-Web. For <strong>the</strong> network provider, it is clearthat high tech capital goods (telecoms network equipment <strong>and</strong> data process<strong>in</strong>gequipment) dom<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts (82%) result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> few trickle-down effects for mostdevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries that don’t have <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>dustries. The service provider has asimilar structure of assets with most <strong>in</strong> network, comput<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> software equipment.Table 1.4: Structure of capital requirements for a fixed l<strong>in</strong>e network provider <strong>and</strong> an Internetservice provider (2000)Item Network Provider Internet Provider(M—Web)Telecoms network equipment 72.5 48.2Data process<strong>in</strong>g equipment 9.5 16.4Software <strong>and</strong> licences - 25.8O<strong>the</strong>r equipment, vehicles, furniture 5.9 9.6L<strong>and</strong> & build<strong>in</strong>gs 5.5 -Work<strong>in</strong>g Capital 6.6 -Total 100.0 100.0Source: Telkom Annual Report 2000, M-Web Annual Report 2000However, <strong>the</strong>re are larger multipliers for ongo<strong>in</strong>g operations. Table 1.5 belowpresents <strong>the</strong> first-round direct <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>direct output multiplier effects of a R1 <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>network provision 1 . The multiplier effects are negligible for <strong>the</strong> primary sectors but1 Data limitations prevent putt<strong>in</strong>g toge<strong>the</strong>r a multiplier analysis for service providers.13


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>significant for <strong>the</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sectors - metal products <strong>and</strong> equipment(transmission <strong>and</strong> receiv<strong>in</strong>g devices); chemicals, rubber <strong>and</strong> plastic products (plasticcas<strong>in</strong>gs for equipment); paper <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>g (market<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> office materials). Thelargest ga<strong>in</strong>s are <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r service <strong>in</strong>dustries, <strong>in</strong> particular, o<strong>the</strong>r communication orbus<strong>in</strong>ess service providers, distribution, transport <strong>and</strong> utilities. A second round ofoutput <strong>and</strong> employment creation can be expected stemm<strong>in</strong>g from additions to wage<strong>and</strong> capital <strong>in</strong>come created by <strong>the</strong> first-round effects.These figures are not high compared to agriculture or manufactur<strong>in</strong>g. Part of <strong>the</strong>reason for this is a low participation of SA <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> communications equipment,with much derived dem<strong>and</strong> go<strong>in</strong>g to imports from o<strong>the</strong>r countries. This may changewith time <strong>and</strong> raise <strong>the</strong> average multiplier effect.Table 1.5: Direct backward l<strong>in</strong>kages – <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> communications <strong>in</strong>dustry(1997) – percentage of total <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put costsSector% of <strong>in</strong>termediate<strong>in</strong>put costsPrimary products 0.0Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g 20.0Natural resource <strong>in</strong>tensive 0.6Labour <strong>in</strong>tensive 2.6Scale <strong>in</strong>tensive 4.5Knowledge <strong>in</strong>tensive 12.1O<strong>the</strong>r 0.2Services 80.0Producer services 44.3Consumer services 20.2Infrastructural services 13.9Community/socialservicesTotal <strong>in</strong>termediates/Total<strong>in</strong>put costs1.622.9Source: Wefa SAM (1997)1.3.3 Medium for Content ProvidersWhat <strong>the</strong> analysis of communication services as an <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put or as a sourceof derived dem<strong>and</strong> fails to convey, is that entire <strong>in</strong>dustries are based around <strong>the</strong>existence of communications services <strong>and</strong> would not exist o<strong>the</strong>rwise - <strong>the</strong>se are <strong>the</strong>content providers. Too often we view <strong>the</strong> communication services as a dem<strong>and</strong>derived from growth <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>dustries or <strong>in</strong> household <strong>in</strong>come. What we fail toappreciate is that <strong>in</strong>novation, cost reduction, quality improvement <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dependentexpansion of communication services enable <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>and</strong> expansion of a largecontent <strong>in</strong>dustry that is transmitted over <strong>the</strong> communications <strong>in</strong>frastructure. Thisprocess is one where <strong>the</strong> communications <strong>in</strong>dustry itself creates dem<strong>and</strong> through<strong>in</strong>novation <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment. The l<strong>in</strong>ks to <strong>the</strong>se content <strong>in</strong>dustries cannot be portrayedusefully by an <strong>in</strong>put-output table.The content providers could most easily be classified accord<strong>in</strong>g to voice, data <strong>and</strong>image/video content. Voice would <strong>in</strong>clude those companies produc<strong>in</strong>g content forradio broadcast - from music to programm<strong>in</strong>g. Video/image would be those produc<strong>in</strong>g14


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>for television or education broadcast - from advertis<strong>in</strong>g to dramas. F<strong>in</strong>ally, datacontent would be associated with those firms provid<strong>in</strong>g content for <strong>the</strong> Internet orprivate data networks - from onl<strong>in</strong>e news corporations to electronic commerce. In all<strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>dustries, expansion of <strong>the</strong> network <strong>and</strong> lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> costs of transmissionexp<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of people connected to <strong>the</strong> network <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore exp<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>market for content. Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> speed <strong>and</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong> networks open up <strong>the</strong>opportunities for new content products to be <strong>in</strong>troduced which also exp<strong>and</strong>s <strong>the</strong>market for content. An important question rema<strong>in</strong>s - how big are <strong>the</strong> multiplier effectson content providers stemm<strong>in</strong>g from improvements to <strong>the</strong> network <strong>and</strong> its expansion.1.3.4 Household Expenditure ItemF<strong>in</strong>ally, communications enter <strong>the</strong> household consumption function. Communicationsdoes not represent one of <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> items that households spend <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>come on, butat 2.4% of household <strong>in</strong>come, it is still a significant item. In fact, as figure 1.2 shows,households on average spend more on communications than on <strong>in</strong>vestments/sav<strong>in</strong>gs, education, house operations, pensions <strong>and</strong> fuel/power. The size ofexpenditure is also sufficiently large that price movements <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector will <strong>in</strong>fluenceboth <strong>the</strong> welfare of consumers <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> price level – <strong>the</strong> consumer price <strong>in</strong>dex. In fact,<strong>the</strong> 1995 survey probably underestimates <strong>the</strong> expenditure item as it would exclude<strong>the</strong> rise <strong>in</strong> cellular telephony <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Internet (both significant expenditure items).Figure 1.2: Household expenditure patterns (1995)15


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>foodhous<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>come taxtransportcloth/footfurniture/equiphealth<strong>in</strong>suranceread/recr/holsdr<strong>in</strong>k/cigspersonal carecommunications<strong>in</strong>vest/sav<strong>in</strong>gseducationhouse operationpensionsdomestic workersfuel/powero<strong>the</strong>r0.64.143.33.32.72.52.42.121.81.61.63.8510.214.716.118.20 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20Percentage of ExpenditureSource: Statistics South Africa, Income <strong>and</strong> Expenditure Survey, 199516


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>2. International Reform of <strong>Telecommunications</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong>2.1 The Rationale for <strong>Regulation</strong><strong>Regulation</strong> is <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tervention of a government body <strong>in</strong> a market, through <strong>the</strong> use ofprice, access or product controls. Price controls occur <strong>in</strong> telecommunications, whereTelkom has to get its tariffs approved by <strong>the</strong> South African regulator, ICASA. Thesame goes for access controls, as ICASA has <strong>the</strong> right to issue licenses for <strong>the</strong>different types of telecomm markets, as it has <strong>in</strong> Telkom for <strong>the</strong> fixed l<strong>in</strong>e market <strong>and</strong>MTN <strong>and</strong> Vodacom for <strong>the</strong> mobile phone market.There are two basic types of <strong>the</strong>ories about regulation we can differentiate: normative<strong>the</strong>ories outl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> response to market failures <strong>and</strong> positive <strong>the</strong>ories describ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>dynamics between policy makers <strong>and</strong> recipients of regulation.2.1.1 Normative Theory of <strong>Regulation</strong>The normative <strong>the</strong>ory postulates that regulation ought to be <strong>in</strong>troduced when <strong>the</strong>re ismarket failure. How market failure is identified <strong>and</strong> how it arises are <strong>the</strong> questionsthat rema<strong>in</strong> to be answered.As to <strong>the</strong> identification of market failure, we identify four types of efficiency that haveto be fulfilled to guarantee an efficient outcome:• Allocative efficiency: occurs when goods are priced at marg<strong>in</strong>al cost, hencesold at <strong>the</strong> true economic cost to <strong>the</strong> producer, without any rents that mayhave been derived from <strong>the</strong> market structure.• Cost efficiency: when a firm or <strong>in</strong>dustry produces at <strong>the</strong> lowest possible costlevel. In some <strong>in</strong>dustries, it may be possible that many competitors lead toallocative efficiency, but that <strong>the</strong> lack of scale effects means production is notcost efficient.• Dynamic efficiency: when cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs are implemented efficiently <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>reis no delay <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> development <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of new products.• Distributional efficiency: f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> socially desired trade-off between <strong>the</strong>maximisation of surplus <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>the</strong>reof.Hav<strong>in</strong>g identified <strong>the</strong> different types of efficiency, <strong>the</strong> ways <strong>in</strong> which market failurearises have to be identified. Here, we identify three basic types:• Externalities: any transaction has a cost <strong>and</strong> a benefit to it. These costs <strong>and</strong>benefits may well differ for <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> society. A car driver, forexample, will not take <strong>in</strong>to account her effects on pollution when plann<strong>in</strong>g atrip. When <strong>the</strong> social costs exceed <strong>the</strong> private costs, or <strong>the</strong> private benefitsexceed <strong>the</strong> social benefits, <strong>the</strong> level of activity is too high. When socialbenefits exceed private benefits, allocation will be lower than desired. Anexample for <strong>the</strong> first would be car usage, an example for <strong>the</strong> second<strong>in</strong>vestment by firms who do not take <strong>in</strong>to account <strong>the</strong> beneficial spill-overs foro<strong>the</strong>r companies. Taxes, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of over allocation, <strong>and</strong> subsidies <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>case of under allocation may be used to rectify <strong>the</strong> situation.17


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>• Natural Monopoly: occurs when it is more expensive to have severalcompanies provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> same product than it is to only have one. Publicutilities, such as water <strong>and</strong> electricity <strong>and</strong> most o<strong>the</strong>r network <strong>in</strong>dustries areclassic examples of natural monopoly. S<strong>in</strong>gle product monopolists will derive<strong>the</strong>ir advantage from economies of scale, whereas multi-product naturalmonopolies may also derive <strong>the</strong>ir advantages from economies of scope 2 .• Large specific <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>and</strong> hold-up problems: when private activity <strong>in</strong>vestslarge amounts <strong>in</strong> assets that may only be used for one purpose, <strong>the</strong>re is apotential for <strong>the</strong> extraction of rents from a contract partner. If a pipel<strong>in</strong>ecompany <strong>in</strong>vests <strong>in</strong> a pipel<strong>in</strong>e from an oil field to a ref<strong>in</strong>ery, this asset is onlygood for transportation between <strong>the</strong>se two po<strong>in</strong>ts. Once it is built, <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>vestment is sunk. The oil field operators might be able to extract <strong>the</strong> sunkcost from <strong>the</strong> pipel<strong>in</strong>e builders should <strong>the</strong>y have o<strong>the</strong>r possibilities for <strong>the</strong>transportation of <strong>the</strong>ir oil. Private contract<strong>in</strong>g may be costly <strong>in</strong> this case <strong>and</strong>regulation <strong>the</strong> preferred tool.<strong>Regulation</strong> must hence be used <strong>in</strong> sectors where competition is not susta<strong>in</strong>able dueto one of <strong>the</strong> three reasons mentioned above. The success of regulation is to bemeasured by <strong>the</strong> efficiency criteria outl<strong>in</strong>ed.2.1.2 Positive Theories for <strong>Regulation</strong><strong>Regulation</strong> does not only exist to correct market failures. This is apparent from <strong>the</strong>fact that regulation cont<strong>in</strong>ues to exist <strong>in</strong> sectors with no natural monopoly features.<strong>Regulation</strong> also exists because it is a powerful means to redistribute wealth <strong>in</strong>society. <strong>Regulation</strong> can be used to tax one group of consumers <strong>and</strong> redistribute toano<strong>the</strong>r without impos<strong>in</strong>g a more transparent tax-subsidy approach (Posner 1971).Classic examples <strong>in</strong> telecommunications are cross subsidisation from long distanceto local calls, from urban areas to rural areas <strong>and</strong> from bus<strong>in</strong>ess users to domesticusers.An alternative to government us<strong>in</strong>g regulation for social welfare-improv<strong>in</strong>gredistribution, is for specific <strong>in</strong>terest groups to capture <strong>the</strong> regulatory process throughlobby<strong>in</strong>g government. Stigler (1971) observed that companies dem<strong>and</strong> regulation <strong>in</strong>an attempt to earn abnormal profits at <strong>the</strong> expense of consumers. Politicians areprone to <strong>in</strong>terest group pressure s<strong>in</strong>ce s<strong>in</strong>gle voters are unable to monitor <strong>and</strong> coerce<strong>the</strong> policy maker. The successful pressure group <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> regulatory game need not becompanies only, but whoever it is <strong>the</strong>y should have low costs of organisation <strong>and</strong>high potential payoffs relative to <strong>the</strong> compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest groups. A good example forthis is <strong>the</strong> success of EU farmers <strong>in</strong> extract<strong>in</strong>g rents from <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> population,whereas consumers with a lower per-head payoff <strong>and</strong> a much larger membershipf<strong>in</strong>d it difficult to extract benefits from policy makers.The same forces that drive politicians to regulate sectors, may also drive <strong>the</strong>m toderegulate. If <strong>in</strong>terest groups that are be<strong>in</strong>g adversely affected by regulation organisemore effectively (or if <strong>the</strong> cost of <strong>the</strong> regulation to <strong>the</strong>m <strong>in</strong>creases enough to make<strong>the</strong>m organise) <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>y may be able to reduce <strong>the</strong> level of regulation. Intelecommunications, <strong>the</strong> advent of <strong>the</strong> Internet has meant that an <strong>in</strong>efficient2 When <strong>the</strong> cost of produc<strong>in</strong>g two products toge<strong>the</strong>r is less than produc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m separately18


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>monopoly has had greater costs to a group of <strong>in</strong>dustry users who have becomeharsh critics of <strong>the</strong> cont<strong>in</strong>ued monopoly.2.2 Different Types of <strong>Regulation</strong>Hav<strong>in</strong>g identified <strong>the</strong> different types of factors that create <strong>the</strong> need for regulation, <strong>and</strong><strong>the</strong> criteria to judge <strong>the</strong> success of regulation, <strong>the</strong> question arises about <strong>the</strong> ways <strong>in</strong>which regulation is adm<strong>in</strong>istered. Here we differentiate between <strong>the</strong>ories forsituations when <strong>the</strong> regulator has perfect <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ories when <strong>the</strong> firm hasmore <strong>in</strong>formation than <strong>the</strong> regulator.2.2.1 <strong>Regulation</strong> under Perfect Information• Marg<strong>in</strong>al Cost (MC) pric<strong>in</strong>g: is possible under <strong>the</strong> case of a weak naturalmonopoly, i.e. one where <strong>the</strong> average cost is upward slop<strong>in</strong>g over some of <strong>the</strong>doma<strong>in</strong>. In this case, MC pric<strong>in</strong>g is possibly efficient• Ramsey Pric<strong>in</strong>g: under strong natural monopoly (i.e. <strong>the</strong> average cost curve isdownward slop<strong>in</strong>g over <strong>the</strong> whole doma<strong>in</strong> reflect<strong>in</strong>g high fixed costs <strong>and</strong> lowmarg<strong>in</strong>al costs), MC pric<strong>in</strong>g will lead to a loss <strong>and</strong> be unsusta<strong>in</strong>able. Amechanism has to be found by which <strong>the</strong> distortion is m<strong>in</strong>imised, given cost isbe<strong>in</strong>g covered.o S<strong>in</strong>gle Product Ramsey Pric<strong>in</strong>g: set price equal to average cost, hencecover<strong>in</strong>g cost at <strong>the</strong> m<strong>in</strong>imum possible distortiono Multi-Product Ramsey Pric<strong>in</strong>g: when elasticities of dem<strong>and</strong> differ <strong>in</strong>different markets, sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> same price-cost markup for both marketsis not optimal, s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> dead weight loss (DWL) is proportionate to <strong>the</strong>elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong>. Hence <strong>the</strong> price-cost mark-up ought to be<strong>in</strong>versely proportionate to <strong>the</strong> price elasticity of dem<strong>and</strong> – i.e. <strong>the</strong>product which whose dem<strong>and</strong> is more sensitive to price changes willhave a lower price-cost markup. In telecommunications, it is oftenassumed that access is <strong>in</strong>elastic <strong>and</strong> usage is elastic. If this is <strong>the</strong> case,<strong>the</strong>n access charges should be high enough to cover most of <strong>the</strong> fixedcosts <strong>and</strong> usage charges extremely low.Clearly, <strong>the</strong> implementation problems associated with MC <strong>and</strong> Ramsey pric<strong>in</strong>g arethose of asymmetric <strong>in</strong>formation. The regulator will have less than complete<strong>in</strong>formation about <strong>the</strong> cost structure of <strong>the</strong> regulated firm, mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> implementationdifficult. Lastly <strong>the</strong>re may be distributional concerns, as those goods that are <strong>in</strong>elasticwill have <strong>the</strong> highest mark-up, but <strong>the</strong>se also tend to be necessities (like basicaccess to a telephone).2.2.2 <strong>Regulation</strong> under Asymmetric InformationIn reality, MC <strong>and</strong> Ramsey pric<strong>in</strong>g will suffer from <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetries betweenregulators <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> firms. Under <strong>the</strong>se circumstances <strong>the</strong> regulator needs to designregulation that overcomes <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetries to provide effectiveregulation. Two types of regulation have been implemented <strong>in</strong> practice. These are:• Rate of Return regulation: this is based on <strong>the</strong> Ramsey idea of hav<strong>in</strong>g pricesset so that <strong>the</strong> firm covers its cost <strong>and</strong> achieves a “fair” return on capital.Hear<strong>in</strong>gs are used to determ<strong>in</strong>e prices after a test year. The problem with this19


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>system is that <strong>the</strong> firm has no <strong>in</strong>centive to cont<strong>in</strong>ually reduce cost. Inflated costis created through <strong>the</strong> attraction of capital ra<strong>the</strong>r than efficiency, an <strong>in</strong>centiveto <strong>in</strong>flate costs before a rate hear<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> need for very detailed regulation.• Incentive regulation: has been created to deal with <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficiencies <strong>in</strong>herent<strong>in</strong> rate of return regulation. There are two basic types of <strong>in</strong>centive regulation:o Price-cap regulation: imposition of a price ceil<strong>in</strong>g on a basket of goods,adjustment of <strong>the</strong> ceil<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> formula CPI-X, where CPI is <strong>the</strong>consumer price <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>and</strong> X is <strong>the</strong> average <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> efficiencyexpected. The potential problem with this mechanism is <strong>the</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>tyabout <strong>the</strong> true level of cost <strong>and</strong> hence <strong>the</strong> crudeness of <strong>the</strong> mechanism.Errors <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dex may lead to w<strong>in</strong>dfall ga<strong>in</strong>s for <strong>the</strong> firms or heavylosses. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive to m<strong>in</strong>imise cost can lead todecreased product quality <strong>and</strong> to <strong>the</strong> elim<strong>in</strong>ation of goods which do notshow potential for efficiency <strong>in</strong>creases.o Earn<strong>in</strong>gs Shar<strong>in</strong>g: whilst price cap regulation achieves cost efficiency,earn<strong>in</strong>gs shar<strong>in</strong>g attempts to strike a balance between cost <strong>and</strong>allocative efficiency. There is a shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> rewards from anydeviation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> rate of return between consumers <strong>and</strong> producers. Theadjusted rate of return is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by a shar<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> deviation from<strong>the</strong> target rate of return ( ra = rt + h( r* − rt), where 0


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>The results are robust <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> way that different model specifications regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>put<strong>and</strong> output prices, as well as us<strong>in</strong>g slightly different data sets do not change <strong>the</strong> basicresults that <strong>in</strong>centive regulation does have beneficial effects on efficiency.A fur<strong>the</strong>r result from <strong>the</strong> modell<strong>in</strong>g is that those regulated companies with <strong>the</strong> highestexpenditures on research <strong>and</strong> development benefited most from <strong>the</strong> change to IR, aresult that is consistent with <strong>in</strong>tuition.Bergman et al (1998) note that more <strong>and</strong> more European countries have started touse price cap regulation, <strong>in</strong>itiated by <strong>the</strong> United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, which <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>the</strong>measure <strong>in</strong> 1988 due to a report by Stephen Littlechild, po<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>g out <strong>the</strong> productive<strong>and</strong> dynamic <strong>in</strong>efficiencies <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> ROR. Among o<strong>the</strong>r states, France, Germany<strong>and</strong> Sweden also <strong>in</strong>troduced PCR <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> early 1990s.Despite <strong>the</strong> positive effects on productive efficiency of PCR, <strong>the</strong>re has been criticismof <strong>the</strong> system relat<strong>in</strong>g to strategic behaviour <strong>and</strong> allocative efficiency. The strategicbehaviour component relates to <strong>the</strong> tim<strong>in</strong>g of rate reviews. To maximise <strong>the</strong> costreduction <strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>the</strong> firms, <strong>the</strong> regulator has to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> time betweenhear<strong>in</strong>gs, such as to allow some appropriation of <strong>the</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s made by sav<strong>in</strong>gs. This,however, <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>the</strong> scope for <strong>the</strong> firm to act strategically: before adjustments,cost sav<strong>in</strong>gs are not fully exploited, so as to signal a lower sav<strong>in</strong>gs potential to <strong>the</strong>regulator. Once <strong>the</strong> new rates have been <strong>in</strong>stalled, maximum sav<strong>in</strong>gs are be<strong>in</strong>gexploited as <strong>the</strong>y can be benefited from for <strong>the</strong> maximum possible time.As to allocative effects, <strong>the</strong> problem is that <strong>the</strong> X-factor is backward look<strong>in</strong>g ra<strong>the</strong>rthan future oriented. The nature of negotiations between <strong>the</strong> regulator <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> firmsdictates that X-factors are based on historical experience ra<strong>the</strong>r than future potential.It is <strong>the</strong> superior knowledge managers have <strong>in</strong> comparison to regulators that makes itpossible for companies to exploit extra profits.Large segments of <strong>the</strong> telecomm <strong>in</strong>dustry are potentially competitive, though, <strong>and</strong> itis thus <strong>the</strong> aim of European policy to liberalise <strong>the</strong>se markets, as effectivecompetition can replace regulation <strong>and</strong> ensure better market outcomes.2.3.2 Liberalis<strong>in</strong>g Network Industries: a Three Stage ProcessThe table below illustrates <strong>the</strong> state of liberalisation of different public services <strong>in</strong>Europe as of spr<strong>in</strong>g 1998 3 :Table 2.1: State of European Deregulation (1998)Germany France Italy Spa<strong>in</strong> Sweden UKAir transport High Medium High Medium↑ High HighElectricity Medium↑ Low↑ Low↑ Medium↑↑ High↑ Very HighPostalservicesMedium↑↑ Low↑ Very Low↑ High↑ Very High Medium↑Rail Low↑ Low↑ Very Low↑ Very Low↑ High Very HighTelecoms Very High High↑ Medium↑↑ High↑ High↑ Very High3 Ibid. p.8021


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>This describes <strong>the</strong> different states that network <strong>in</strong>dustries were <strong>in</strong> at that moment <strong>in</strong>time. As <strong>the</strong> system evolves towards a more liberalised system, <strong>the</strong>re are differentdem<strong>and</strong>s on regulation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> different phases. The book differentiates between threephases:1. Monopoly2. Monopoly <strong>and</strong> <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>in</strong> some Markets3. <strong>Competition</strong>Figure 2.2: Path of Regulatory IntensityPhase 1 Phase 2 Phase 3RegulatoryIntensityPhase 1The problems associated with an <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> phase 1 of liberalisation are best dealtwith through <strong>the</strong> measures outl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous sections: close regulation of <strong>the</strong>monopolist to ensure productive <strong>and</strong> allocative efficiency. Ramsey pric<strong>in</strong>g would be<strong>the</strong> preferred measure under perfect <strong>in</strong>formation, but is not possible due to <strong>the</strong>impossibility to access accurate data for effective regulation. ROR has <strong>the</strong> problemsassociated with over <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> capital expenditure to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> absolute levelof profits allowed <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> lack of <strong>in</strong>centives for cost reduction. Regulatory lag could,however, provide limited <strong>in</strong>centives for cost reduction, as <strong>the</strong> rate of return would behigher for <strong>the</strong> period between rate reviews. PCR, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong> leads to efficientproduction, but lacks on <strong>the</strong> allocative side due to <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetries about <strong>the</strong>true efficiency potential of <strong>the</strong> firm.Phase 2TimeHere, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>in</strong>troduction of competition <strong>in</strong> some parts of <strong>the</strong> operations. It ispossible that effective competition will never be possible <strong>in</strong> all parts of <strong>the</strong> operations,as duplication of some network components may not be viable <strong>in</strong> all fields. Intelecommunications, for example, fibre-optic backbones are existent on differentnetworks <strong>in</strong> some countries, but <strong>the</strong>re hardly ever is any duplication of “<strong>the</strong> last mile”,i.e. <strong>the</strong> connection from <strong>the</strong> user’s premises to <strong>the</strong> local exchange. The viability forduplication of <strong>the</strong>se parts is not given.In <strong>the</strong> second phase of liberalisation, <strong>the</strong>re are three str<strong>and</strong>s of activities that have tobe pursued: firstly <strong>the</strong> separation of <strong>the</strong> regulator from <strong>the</strong> monopolist, secondly <strong>the</strong>regulation of <strong>in</strong>cumbent pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> thirdly <strong>the</strong> regulation of <strong>in</strong>terconnection.As to <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dependence of <strong>the</strong> regulator, it has to be ensured that <strong>the</strong>re is no captureof <strong>the</strong> regulator for any of <strong>the</strong> parties <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market. This is important to <strong>in</strong>stil22


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>confidence <strong>in</strong> any companies wish<strong>in</strong>g to enter <strong>the</strong> market, provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m with <strong>the</strong>certa<strong>in</strong>ty that <strong>the</strong>y will have a level play<strong>in</strong>g field.On <strong>the</strong> front of price regulation, <strong>the</strong> monopolist has <strong>the</strong> possibility to use rents frommonopoly markets to subsidise activities <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitive markets <strong>and</strong> thus ga<strong>in</strong> anunfair advantage. The importance <strong>the</strong>refore lies <strong>in</strong> analys<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> level <strong>and</strong> structureof prices set by <strong>the</strong> monopolist.Network <strong>in</strong>dustries have a large part of <strong>the</strong>ir cost <strong>in</strong> fixed components, mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>allocation of costs to services very difficult <strong>and</strong> arbitrary. Considerable effort thus hasto be expended towards <strong>the</strong> analysis of <strong>the</strong> cost structure <strong>and</strong> to <strong>the</strong> development ofa “fair” level of prices to be set by <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitive market.Deviations <strong>in</strong> both directions are potentially damag<strong>in</strong>g: sett<strong>in</strong>g prices too low willdiscourage entry by firms even it <strong>the</strong>y were more efficient than <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent. Shouldprices be set too high, <strong>the</strong>n entrants will be able to enter even if <strong>the</strong>y are less efficientthan <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, it will jeopardise <strong>the</strong> profitability of <strong>the</strong> company<strong>and</strong> thus <strong>the</strong> cross subsidies to unprofitable market segments necessary for universalservice obligations.Even <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> most competitive telecomm markets, such as Germany 4 , not all aspectsof <strong>the</strong> network have been subjected to competition, such as <strong>the</strong> last mile. There isstrong controversy about <strong>the</strong> correct level of <strong>in</strong>terconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g between <strong>the</strong>network components of Deutsche Telekom <strong>and</strong> its competitors. Once aga<strong>in</strong>, <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>centives of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent <strong>and</strong> competitors are opposed. If <strong>in</strong>terconnection pricesare set too high, <strong>the</strong> monopolist will receive an overly high amount for <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>terconnection services <strong>and</strong> thus deter entry by efficient companies. Should <strong>the</strong>prices be set too low, however, this will also attract <strong>in</strong>efficient entry. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, itwill discourage <strong>in</strong>vestment by <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent <strong>in</strong>to new technologies, as entrantsconsequently do not carry a “fair” share of costs <strong>and</strong> risks of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>and</strong>benefit disproportionately from <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent’s <strong>in</strong>vestments.When <strong>in</strong>terconnect<strong>in</strong>g networks, <strong>the</strong>re are different possibilities to design accessprices:• Efficient Component Pric<strong>in</strong>g Rule (ECPR): this mechanism warrants entry aslong as <strong>the</strong> entrant is at least as efficient as <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent. It is assumed thatretail prices are fixed, i.e. that allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> entrant access does not have aneffect on <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent’s price. The cost structure is def<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>the</strong> average<strong>in</strong>cremental cost of access, b, <strong>the</strong> average <strong>in</strong>cremental cost of provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>competitive part of <strong>the</strong> service, c, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> retail price of <strong>the</strong> service, p. Theoptimal access price is thus def<strong>in</strong>ed as: a = b + [ p - (b + c)]. In <strong>the</strong> context of along-distance telephone context, b would be <strong>the</strong> cost of connect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>customer from her home to <strong>the</strong> local exchange <strong>and</strong> c <strong>the</strong> cost of rout<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>call on backbone <strong>in</strong>frastructure. The problem associated with <strong>the</strong> ECPR is <strong>the</strong>fact that allocative effects are be<strong>in</strong>g ignored, due to <strong>the</strong> assumptions of ahomogenous fixed product, a fixed coefficient of technology <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ability ofcompetitors to bypass <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent.• Ramsey access pric<strong>in</strong>g: <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> spirit of optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g for society, Ramseyaccess pric<strong>in</strong>g also takes some allocative effects <strong>in</strong>to account. The formula for<strong>the</strong> calculation of <strong>the</strong> access price changes to: a = b + σ(p – (b + c)). σ is what4 Purton (2000), SURVEY - FT TELECOMMS: Former monopoly loses significant market share23


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>is called <strong>the</strong> displacement ratio, namely “<strong>the</strong> change <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent’s retailprices as access prices vary” divided by “<strong>the</strong> change <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent’s salesof access services to its rival as <strong>the</strong> access charge varies”. When <strong>the</strong> threeassumptions quoted above hold, <strong>the</strong>n σ=1, o<strong>the</strong>rwise σ


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>In <strong>the</strong> three phases of liberalisation, <strong>the</strong>re are different challenges for <strong>the</strong> regulator. Inphase 1, classical regulation challenges are to be dealt with, i.e. achiev<strong>in</strong>gproductive, allocative <strong>and</strong> dynamic efficiency. Once competition is <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong>phase 2, <strong>the</strong> regulator has to deal more with <strong>the</strong> behaviour of <strong>in</strong>cumbents <strong>and</strong>entrants toward each o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> abuse of market power by <strong>in</strong>cumbents, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>provision of “fair” access prices for entrants to non-competitive parts of <strong>the</strong> network.In phase 3, regulation becomes more light-h<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> revolves around <strong>the</strong> fairdistribution of universal access obligations <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> adherence to fair trad<strong>in</strong>gpractises, s<strong>in</strong>ce competition takes care of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r aspects of regulat<strong>in</strong>g price <strong>and</strong>entry.2.4 Convergence <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Over <strong>the</strong> past decade, telecommunication has been subjected to a technologicalrevolution, decreas<strong>in</strong>g natural monopoly characteristics of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>and</strong> creat<strong>in</strong>gnew markets <strong>in</strong> mobile telephony, <strong>the</strong> use of <strong>the</strong> Internet <strong>and</strong> wireless local looptechnologies.Whereas <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> past, <strong>the</strong> market to be regulated was clearly def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>and</strong> regulation ofplayers revolved more around technical regulation, today <strong>the</strong> market boundarieshave become blurred. <strong>Competition</strong> has <strong>the</strong> potential to decrease <strong>the</strong> need forregulation <strong>in</strong> some of <strong>the</strong> more competitive markets, but has <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>the</strong> potentialfor asymmetric regulation. Whereas <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> past <strong>the</strong> emphasis was laid on efficiency<strong>and</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>cipal-agent problems of <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> correct behaviour <strong>in</strong> regulated utilities,nowadays <strong>the</strong> problems lie more <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> area of dom<strong>in</strong>ance of <strong>in</strong>cumbents, a lack ofmarket boundaries, <strong>the</strong> pace of technological change <strong>in</strong>fluenc<strong>in</strong>g cost <strong>and</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>tyabout future technologies.In <strong>the</strong> past, <strong>the</strong> more concentrated regulation of s<strong>in</strong>gle sectors was by nature def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> rules of play <strong>and</strong> creat<strong>in</strong>g competitive environments. In <strong>the</strong> present context,however, competition agencies have ga<strong>in</strong>ed greater importance, observ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>markets <strong>and</strong> act<strong>in</strong>g ex-post only if <strong>the</strong>re is evidence of anti-competitive behaviour.An example of classic sectoral regulation is that of OFTEL, <strong>the</strong> UK office fortelecommunications regulation. In Malaysia, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, regulation of <strong>the</strong>entire broadcast<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry has been attributed a s<strong>in</strong>gle agency, deal<strong>in</strong>g with alltelecommunications <strong>and</strong> broadcast issues.25


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>3. Current Regulatory FrameworkThe most crucial factor <strong>in</strong>fluenc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>and</strong> performance of <strong>the</strong>market is <strong>the</strong> regulatory regime. This section exam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> regulation of <strong>the</strong>telecommunications market <strong>in</strong> South Africa as a basis for <strong>the</strong> discussion ofstructure <strong>and</strong> conduct <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> next section.3.1 Background <strong>and</strong> Objectives of Current <strong>Regulation</strong>The momentum towards restructur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> telecommunications market <strong>in</strong>South Africa came <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> late 1980s when <strong>the</strong> previous government<strong>in</strong>vestigated <strong>the</strong> option of hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> public telecommunications managed asa commercial enterprise. The momentum came from both observation ofchanges <strong>in</strong>ternationally <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>in</strong>efficiencies <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> delivery ofcommunications services locally resulted <strong>in</strong> poor returns to capital <strong>and</strong> ris<strong>in</strong>gdebt – h<strong>in</strong>der<strong>in</strong>g its ability to serve <strong>the</strong> needs of a grow<strong>in</strong>g modern economy.After Telkom was <strong>in</strong>corporated <strong>in</strong> 1990, a study by Coopers & Lybr<strong>and</strong> was<strong>in</strong>itiated to exam<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> policy options for restructur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry tomaximise <strong>the</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> social benefit, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g improv<strong>in</strong>g telephonepenetration, affordability <strong>and</strong> service levels. The recommendations of <strong>the</strong>report, released <strong>in</strong> 1992, <strong>in</strong>cluded most of <strong>the</strong> elements of <strong>the</strong> eventualregulatory regime enacted <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Act of 1996. These<strong>in</strong>cluded an exclusivity period for Telkom, resale of capacity for voice trafficprevented for 3-5 years, str<strong>in</strong>gent licence conditions for Telkom dur<strong>in</strong>g thisperiod of exclusivity, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> establishment of an <strong>in</strong>dependent regulator. Italso <strong>in</strong>cluded a call for some immediate steps to be taken – <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>issu<strong>in</strong>g of two mobile communications licences <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> open<strong>in</strong>g up of <strong>the</strong>VANS <strong>and</strong> customer equipment markets.The government acted on <strong>the</strong> mobile licences (issued June 1994) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>open<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> VANS <strong>and</strong> customer equipment markets (1993). However, <strong>the</strong>major revamp of <strong>the</strong> regulatory regime would have to wait for a change <strong>in</strong>government <strong>and</strong> a process of broad consultation through a Green/WhitePaper process. The White Paper was only released <strong>in</strong> March 1996 <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ensu<strong>in</strong>g legislation enacted <strong>in</strong> November 1996. This meant that although afive-year monopoly period was recommended for Telkom back <strong>in</strong> 1992, thatmonopoly period only began to take effect <strong>in</strong> 1997.The Green/White Paper process did, however, contribute to <strong>the</strong> f<strong>in</strong>alregulatory outcome because it <strong>in</strong>cluded a number of objectives o<strong>the</strong>r than<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g competition, efficiency, <strong>in</strong>novation <strong>and</strong> profitability <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry.In particular it called for <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g social goals to be part of <strong>the</strong> objectivesof a telecommunications policy:• promote <strong>the</strong> universal <strong>and</strong> affordable provision of telecommunicationservices;• ensure that, <strong>in</strong> relation to <strong>the</strong> provision of telecommunication services, <strong>the</strong>needs of <strong>the</strong> local communities <strong>and</strong> areas are duly taken <strong>in</strong>to account;• encourage ownership <strong>and</strong> control of telecommunication services bypersons from historically disadvantaged groups;26


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>• encourage <strong>the</strong> development of human resources <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry;• promote small, medium <strong>and</strong> micro-enterprises with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry;These are <strong>the</strong> public <strong>in</strong>terest considerations that permit <strong>the</strong> deviation ofregulation from full promotion of competition. The most important economicgoals expressed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> objectives were:• promote <strong>the</strong> provision of a wide range of telecommunication services <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest of <strong>the</strong> economic growth <strong>and</strong> development of <strong>the</strong> Republic;• encourage <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry;• encourage <strong>the</strong> development of a competitive <strong>and</strong> effectivetelecommunications manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> supply sector;• ensure fair competition with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry;• ensure efficient use of <strong>the</strong> radio frequency spectrum;3.2 Independent Regulatory Body – SATRA to ICASAAn important component of <strong>the</strong> new telecommunications regulation was <strong>the</strong>establishment of an <strong>in</strong>dependent regulatory body, a function that used toreside with <strong>the</strong> Department of Communications <strong>and</strong> Telkom. The new body,<strong>the</strong> South African <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Regulatory Authority (SATRA),consisted of 3 to 5 councillors <strong>and</strong> one chairperson, all Presidentialappo<strong>in</strong>tments based on <strong>the</strong> recommendations from a parliamentarycommittee. The act specifically excludes people who may have conflict<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>terests such as a f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry itself, <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>s that<strong>the</strong> committee be representative of <strong>the</strong> population <strong>and</strong> with sufficient expertiseamongst <strong>the</strong>m. The councillors are appo<strong>in</strong>ted for 4 years <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> chairperson5 years. The council can appo<strong>in</strong>t a sizeable staff <strong>and</strong> occasional consultantsto assist it <strong>in</strong> perform<strong>in</strong>g its function. In 2000 SATRA was merged with <strong>the</strong> IBA(Independent Broadcast<strong>in</strong>g Authority) to form ICASA (IndependentCommunications Authority of South Africa). The rationale beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> movewas <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g convergence of broadcast<strong>in</strong>g, telecommunications <strong>and</strong>comput<strong>in</strong>g.The source of fund<strong>in</strong>g is an important determ<strong>in</strong>ant of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dependence of <strong>the</strong>regulator. The <strong>in</strong>tent of <strong>the</strong> regulation was that <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> long run SATRA/ICASAwould be wholly f<strong>in</strong>anced through various licence <strong>and</strong> tender fees from <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>dustry itself. This would give <strong>the</strong> Authority an important f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>dependence from <strong>the</strong> Department of Communications (DoC). However,currently <strong>the</strong> Authority requires supplementary f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g through <strong>the</strong> budget ofDoC subject to <strong>the</strong> usual approval of parliament. The telecommunications<strong>in</strong>dustry has perceived <strong>the</strong> ty<strong>in</strong>g of SATRA/ICASA fund<strong>in</strong>g to DoC as animportant loss of <strong>in</strong>dependence as its actions may be subject to political<strong>in</strong>terference. ICASA acknowledges that it is under-resourced <strong>and</strong> so unable toregulate <strong>the</strong> sector properly (Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Report January 2001). This isproblematic enough while <strong>the</strong>y are manag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Telkom monopoly position,but is very worry<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong> future when regulation becomes more complex(phas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> competition <strong>and</strong> regulat<strong>in</strong>g access <strong>and</strong> retail prices more closely).27


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>The purpose of SATRA/ICASA is to regulate <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong><strong>Telecommunications</strong> Act (1996) <strong>and</strong> pursue any new policy directions that areissued by <strong>the</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ister of Communications as long as <strong>the</strong>y are consistent with<strong>the</strong> broad objectives expressed above <strong>and</strong> if prior consultation has takenplace. Many aspects of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Act provided only limitedguidance <strong>and</strong> regulatory pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>and</strong> so much of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>itial work ofSATRA/ICASA was to put some concrete guidel<strong>in</strong>es toge<strong>the</strong>r for <strong>the</strong> purposeof regulation. The regulatory aspects left to <strong>the</strong> discretion of <strong>the</strong> regulator<strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong>terconnection, facilities leas<strong>in</strong>g, GPMCS (global personal mobilecommunications services) <strong>and</strong> licence conditions.Despite this show of <strong>in</strong>dependence, <strong>the</strong> Act permits <strong>the</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ister ofCommunications to amend, withdraw or substitute any decision by <strong>the</strong>regulator. This provision has already been used by DoC to withdraw SATRA’sguidel<strong>in</strong>es on <strong>in</strong>terconnection <strong>and</strong> facilities leas<strong>in</strong>g. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> implication of<strong>the</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ister sett<strong>in</strong>g policy means that <strong>the</strong> shape of deregulation is left to <strong>the</strong>M<strong>in</strong>ister. Although <strong>the</strong> White Paper provides guidel<strong>in</strong>es for deregulation, it issubject to review by <strong>the</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ister who also is entrusted with sett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> datesfor which segments of <strong>the</strong> market are opened for competition, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> numberof new entrants. The regulator role is merely to call for tenders for licences<strong>and</strong> issue licences accord<strong>in</strong>g to fair <strong>and</strong> transparent criteria.SATRA/ICASA has lost credibility <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry as both <strong>in</strong>dependent <strong>and</strong>effective through failure <strong>in</strong> a number of crucial regulatory episodes. The first<strong>in</strong>cident occurred shortly after <strong>the</strong> passage of <strong>the</strong> Act, when Telkom claimedthat <strong>the</strong> Internet was a basic service <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore fell under its exclusivityagreement. Although SATRA eventually ruled that this was not <strong>the</strong> case,Telkom took <strong>the</strong> challenge to <strong>the</strong> courts ensur<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong> matter dragged onano<strong>the</strong>r 6 months.The second major <strong>in</strong>cident was <strong>the</strong> as yet unsuccessful issu<strong>in</strong>g of a thirdcellular licence through a ‘beauty contest’ process. SATRA made arecommendation for Cell C to be awarded <strong>the</strong> licence, go<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>the</strong>external consultant’s recommendations. One of <strong>the</strong> los<strong>in</strong>g bidders, Nextcom,challenged <strong>the</strong> outcome <strong>and</strong> has succeeded <strong>in</strong> delay<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> process <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>courts for over a year. In <strong>the</strong> process, it has been alleged that <strong>the</strong>re waspolitical <strong>in</strong>terference <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> licens<strong>in</strong>g process, erod<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> credibility of SATRAas an <strong>in</strong>dependent body.F<strong>in</strong>ally, Telkom accused VANS operators of illegally provid<strong>in</strong>g telephony to<strong>the</strong>ir clients <strong>in</strong> contravention of <strong>the</strong> Act. The action it took was to deny fur<strong>the</strong>rcapacity to <strong>the</strong>m <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> some cases withhold services. SATRA ruled aga<strong>in</strong>st<strong>the</strong> unilateral action by Telkom but was duly ignored by <strong>the</strong> operator. Theissue has been partly resolved after AT&T threatened to take <strong>the</strong> issue to <strong>the</strong>WTO where South Africa has committed to an open<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> VANS sector<strong>and</strong> to a telecommunications reference paper that upholds action aga<strong>in</strong>st anticompetitivepractice by <strong>in</strong>dustry players.28


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>3.3 Fixed l<strong>in</strong>e Networks3.3.1 Local AccessThe atta<strong>in</strong>ment of social objectives played an important role <strong>in</strong> decid<strong>in</strong>g howto regulate <strong>the</strong> fixed l<strong>in</strong>e market. It was felt that rapid <strong>in</strong>frastructure rollout topreviously under-serviced areas was critical to <strong>the</strong> promotion of universalservice <strong>and</strong> economic empowerment. As <strong>the</strong>se areas are generally ei<strong>the</strong>r low<strong>in</strong>comeor rural, <strong>the</strong> feel<strong>in</strong>g was that immediate competition <strong>in</strong> fixed l<strong>in</strong>eservices would not serve <strong>the</strong> objectives best. The reason<strong>in</strong>g was:• new entrants would target <strong>the</strong> more lucrative <strong>and</strong> easily establishedbus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong> long-distance markets first <strong>and</strong> not seek to rollout <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>seunder-serviced areas,• competition <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se markets would squeeze <strong>the</strong> profitability of Telkom <strong>and</strong>so limit its own ability to rollout <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se unprofitable areas, <strong>and</strong>• <strong>the</strong> option of contributions to a universal service fund was not desirableuntil basic exchange <strong>in</strong>frastructure was <strong>in</strong> place <strong>in</strong> some areas to whichlow <strong>in</strong>come households could be more cheaply connected.This co<strong>in</strong>cided with <strong>the</strong> need to restructure Telkom itself to face competition –such as improv<strong>in</strong>g efficiency <strong>and</strong> rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g its tariffs to remove crosssubsidisation.It is also felt that <strong>the</strong> grant<strong>in</strong>g of an exclusivity period helped toraise <strong>the</strong> market value of Telkom allow<strong>in</strong>g for a better price on <strong>the</strong> equity sale.For <strong>the</strong>se reasons, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Act gave Telkom a regulatedmonopoly for five years, extendable to six, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> local access market. Toensure that <strong>the</strong> exclusivity period fulfilled <strong>the</strong> goals of <strong>in</strong>frastructure rollout <strong>and</strong>prepar<strong>in</strong>g Telkom for competition, strict licence conditions were placed on <strong>the</strong>network provider. The licence conditions <strong>in</strong>cluded roll<strong>in</strong>g out 2.81 million newl<strong>in</strong>es over <strong>the</strong> exclusivity period, of which 2/3rds will be <strong>in</strong> under-servicedareas <strong>and</strong> for priority customers. It is estimated that this will require capital<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> region of R53 billion. The specific rollout targets arepresented <strong>in</strong> table 3.1 below. The only part of local access network that is notcovered by <strong>the</strong> exclusivity agreement is customer premises equipment (CPE),which was opened to full competition immediately on pass<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Act.Telkom w<strong>in</strong>s an extra year of exclusivity if by <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> fourth year it hasachieved a roll-out of 90% of its cumulative five-year total l<strong>in</strong>e target <strong>and</strong> 80%of its five-year under-serviced l<strong>in</strong>e target. This will be granted if Telkomaccepts a new five-year total of three million new l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>and</strong> a proportionate<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> its under-serviced l<strong>in</strong>e target. There are f<strong>in</strong>ancial penalties forfail<strong>in</strong>g to reach <strong>the</strong>se targets. Telkom pays penalties of R450 per l<strong>in</strong>e for <strong>the</strong>first 100,000 <strong>and</strong> R900 per l<strong>in</strong>e for each extra l<strong>in</strong>e missed. If it misses PriorityCustomer targets <strong>the</strong> penalty per unit is R4,500, schools R900, publicpayphones R2,250 <strong>and</strong> villages R1,125.29


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Table 3.1: Rollout Targets for Telkom <strong>in</strong> terms of License1997/8 1998/92001 2002 Total1999/2000Total new access l<strong>in</strong>es 340000 435000 575000 675000 665000 2690000bought <strong>in</strong>to serviceNo. <strong>in</strong> under-serviced 265000 318000 359000 357000 378000 1677000areasNo. for priority 3240 3845 4055 5060 4046 20246customersNo. of villages served 510 610 610 800 644 3174No. of payphones 20000 25000 25000 25000 25000 120000No. of replacement l<strong>in</strong>es 20000 13000 65000 551000 603000 1252000Source: JEDPIn addition to <strong>the</strong>se rollout targets, Telkom is committed to upgrad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>network <strong>and</strong> its service record. This <strong>in</strong>volves upgrad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> entire network todigital by 2000, lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> wait<strong>in</strong>g period for <strong>in</strong>stallation, lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>number of faults per 100 l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>and</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> time to fix faults. The licencealso allows for restrictions on price <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong>troduced by Telkom to ensurethat its monopoly position is not abused dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> exclusivity period. Theseare set for a bundle of services (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g local, long-distance <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational) <strong>and</strong> are restricted to <strong>the</strong> CPI -1.5% for <strong>the</strong> first three years, afterwhich SATRA will set price caps.The White Paper on telecommunications suggested that once exclusivity hasended, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>in</strong>itially <strong>the</strong> local loop should be open to entry with operatorsconnect<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> PSTN of Telkom (see figure 3.1). The th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g was thatentry was unlikely anyway but co-operative organisations or SMMEs might bewill<strong>in</strong>g to connect specific communities <strong>and</strong> so be encouraged. After a fur<strong>the</strong>ryear, it was envisaged that a full switch<strong>in</strong>g network could be licenced <strong>in</strong>competition to Telkom, provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> local exchanges too. The exact shape ofderegulation is currently under review. However, <strong>the</strong> tim<strong>in</strong>g of issu<strong>in</strong>g asecond PSTN licence is bound <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> WTO <strong>and</strong> must be complete before <strong>the</strong>end of 2003.30


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Figure 3.1: Proposed path of deregulationEnd ofTelkom’sexclusivity1 2 3 4 5 6Radio (pag<strong>in</strong>g, trunk<strong>in</strong>g, etcCellular NetworksCPEVANSFull<strong>Competition</strong>National long distance servicesResaleLicenced carriersLocal LoopBus<strong>in</strong>ess LLTelephony LLInternational servicesSwtich<strong>in</strong>g NetworksRepresents Telkom exclusivitySource: White Paper on <strong>Telecommunications</strong>3.3.2 Long-distanceLong distance was bundled toge<strong>the</strong>r with local access <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> grant<strong>in</strong>g ofexclusivity to Telkom until a review of policy <strong>and</strong> a subsequent call from <strong>the</strong>M<strong>in</strong>ister to proceed with licens<strong>in</strong>g. The <strong>in</strong>itial th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> White Paper wasto <strong>in</strong>troduce <strong>the</strong> licenced resale of long distance facilities operated by Telkomby 2000. Two years later it was envisaged that <strong>the</strong> regulator could licencelong-distance carriers with <strong>the</strong>ir own facilities but who connected to <strong>the</strong>Telkom PSTN. F<strong>in</strong>ally, a full service PSTN would be licenced by 2003.Currently <strong>the</strong> resale has not materialised <strong>and</strong> we await <strong>the</strong> decision on o<strong>the</strong>rlicenc<strong>in</strong>g. Any licence holder would be eligible for universal service fundcontributions, human resource contributions <strong>and</strong> a licence fee of 1% ofturnover. There may be additional conditions attached but <strong>the</strong>se are unlikelyto exceed any that Telkom would have to bear.3.3.3 Value-added Network Services (VANS)Value added network services by def<strong>in</strong>ition do not have facilities of <strong>the</strong>ir ownbut lease from network providers. The sector has been open s<strong>in</strong>ce 1993 withlicence holders required to lease Telkom capacity <strong>and</strong> are prevented from <strong>the</strong>resale of capacity <strong>and</strong> of carry<strong>in</strong>g voice traffic, until a date set by <strong>the</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ister.The White Paper envisaged resale to commence <strong>in</strong> year 4 of exclusivity(2000) but it has not materialised. The licence conditions also <strong>in</strong>clude noundertak<strong>in</strong>g of anti-competitive practices <strong>and</strong> adher<strong>in</strong>g to practices thatprotect <strong>the</strong> customer. They are also eligible for a universal service <strong>and</strong> humanresource fund contributions.31


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>3.3.4 Private Networks (voice)Eskom <strong>and</strong> Transnet both have large private networks that could potentiallybe used <strong>in</strong> competition to Telkom. In fact, it is widely believed that one of<strong>the</strong>se two would likely get <strong>the</strong> second public switched licence <strong>in</strong> partnershipwith an empowerment group <strong>and</strong> an <strong>in</strong>ternational operator. There are evenmoves at this po<strong>in</strong>t to comb<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> two <strong>in</strong>to a s<strong>in</strong>gle corporate entity. Theyhave <strong>the</strong> advantage of not only hav<strong>in</strong>g a large exist<strong>in</strong>g network, but alsoextensive transmission networks over which to layout a new communicationsnetwork. There are also numerous o<strong>the</strong>r private networks that operate with<strong>in</strong>a corporation on <strong>the</strong>ir l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> lease capacity from <strong>the</strong> PSTN. The WhitePaper envisaged that resale of leased capacity could occur <strong>in</strong> year 4. This hasnot happened.In terms of <strong>the</strong> Act, a licence is required to operate a private network thatextends beyond <strong>the</strong> boundaries of l<strong>and</strong> owned by <strong>the</strong> corporation, except forTransnet or Eskom. No such licences are available until notice from <strong>the</strong>M<strong>in</strong>ister. In addition, <strong>in</strong> order to limit <strong>the</strong> potential competition from Transnet<strong>and</strong> Eskom at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> exclusivity period, or at <strong>the</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t where resale ofcapacity is allowed, <strong>the</strong> Act states that nei<strong>the</strong>r of <strong>the</strong>se two may “<strong>in</strong>stall orextend <strong>the</strong>ir telecommunication facilities so as to cause unnecessaryduplication of such facilities with <strong>the</strong> telecommunication facilities of Telkom, orembark on any major <strong>in</strong>stallation or extension of <strong>the</strong>ir telecommunicationfacilities, without <strong>the</strong> proposed <strong>in</strong>stallation or extension <strong>in</strong> question hav<strong>in</strong>gbeen referred to a liaison committee”. The liaison committee <strong>in</strong>cludes Telkom<strong>and</strong> so <strong>the</strong>y must authorise network expansion. If agreement is not met,SATRA may <strong>in</strong>tervene <strong>and</strong> make a decision on network expansion.3.4 Mobile communications3.4.1 CellularThe <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Act recognises <strong>the</strong> licences of Vodacom <strong>and</strong> MTNto operate a cellular network. It also requires that with<strong>in</strong> two years SATRA<strong>in</strong>vestigate <strong>the</strong> feasibility of issu<strong>in</strong>g more licences. This has occurred <strong>and</strong> onemore licence was due to be awarded <strong>in</strong> early 2000 (currently pend<strong>in</strong>g).SATRA is required to conduct a fur<strong>the</strong>r feasibility study for a fourth cellularlicence by July 2001. The Act allows SATRA to establish licence conditionsfor any licence that may help achieve <strong>the</strong> objectives laid out above. Thusfar<strong>the</strong>y have <strong>in</strong>cluded limitations on foreign ownership, requirement to have aBlack empowerment partner, economic development through local purchas<strong>in</strong>g<strong>and</strong> exports, universal service obligations (beyond USF contributions) <strong>and</strong>human resource development. The scheme developed for <strong>the</strong> cellularlicences was to attach values to certa<strong>in</strong> development actions for which <strong>the</strong>network operators were credited. The requirement was for a credit amount<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> licence holder could choose <strong>the</strong> mix of activities that fulfilled thisobligation.In addition, <strong>the</strong>re were some specific service conditions:32


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>• MTN <strong>and</strong> Vodacom were required to <strong>in</strong>stall 7,500 <strong>and</strong> 22,000 communityservice telephones respectively to under-serviced areas over a period offive years• Achieve a population coverage of 60% with<strong>in</strong> 2 years <strong>and</strong> 70% with<strong>in</strong> 4years.• Price <strong>in</strong>creases limited to <strong>the</strong> CPI or below <strong>in</strong> any one yearThe conditions for a new licence have similar requirements but have beenrelaxed to attract <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>vestors. In particular, <strong>the</strong> new entrant will beallowed domestic roam<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> MTN <strong>and</strong> Vodacom networks to provide<strong>the</strong>m with extensive coverage while <strong>the</strong>ir network is be<strong>in</strong>g rolled out <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ywill be protected from fur<strong>the</strong>r new entrants for 5 years. There is also nospecified sharehold<strong>in</strong>g size for <strong>the</strong> required empowerment partner.The Act also recognises that <strong>in</strong> order to provide a cellular service, <strong>the</strong> licenceholders will need to provide long-distance <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational services, oftenthrough alternative technologies (satellite or fixed l<strong>in</strong>e). To protect <strong>the</strong> Telkommonopoly, <strong>the</strong> cellular providers are not allowed to make use of any fixedl<strong>in</strong>es o<strong>the</strong>r than those from Telkom, <strong>and</strong> all <strong>in</strong>ternational services must berouted through <strong>the</strong> Telkom network. They are of course free to negotiate<strong>in</strong>ternational roam<strong>in</strong>g services for when <strong>the</strong> consumer is out of <strong>the</strong> country.The key structural issue for <strong>the</strong> cellular <strong>in</strong>dustry is <strong>the</strong> separation of networkfrom service provider. The network providers provide wholesale airtime toretailers who <strong>the</strong>n retail this airtime to customers on a per m<strong>in</strong>ute basis. Thisseparation has been <strong>the</strong> regulatory path <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK <strong>and</strong> makes regulationeasier as <strong>the</strong> focus becomes regulation of <strong>the</strong> network provision <strong>and</strong> not anypotential abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> service supply component stemm<strong>in</strong>g fromvertical <strong>in</strong>tegration.3.4.2 SatelliteSatellite networks can be used for transmission of national long-distance <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational traffic, as well as Global Mobile Personal Communications. AsTelkom does not have any satellite network itself, <strong>the</strong> network provision isopen to competition. However, <strong>in</strong> order to protect <strong>the</strong> Telkom monopoly on<strong>in</strong>ternational traffic, all signal distribution for <strong>in</strong>com<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> outgo<strong>in</strong>g calls to SAthrough earth stations must take place through <strong>the</strong> Telkom service provider. In<strong>the</strong> event that <strong>the</strong> Satellite network is able to bypass <strong>the</strong> Telkom facilitiesthrough satellite-to-satellite l<strong>in</strong>ks or earth stations positioned outside <strong>the</strong>borders, a bypass fee must be paid. This fee has yet to be negotiated. Thisarrangement will end when Telkom exclusivity ends.3.5 Interconnection, Facilities Leas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Number<strong>in</strong>gInterconnection is crucial to a competitive environment as <strong>the</strong> value of anetwork depends on <strong>the</strong> number of subscribers. It is also necessary for aseparation of service providers from network providers. Under <strong>the</strong> Act <strong>and</strong>subsequent guidel<strong>in</strong>es issued by SATRA, <strong>in</strong>terconnection with a majorprovider is ensured• At any technically feasible po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> network,33


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>• Under non-discrim<strong>in</strong>atory terms,• In a timely fashion under conditions that are transparent <strong>and</strong> fair, <strong>and</strong>• At rates determ<strong>in</strong>ed by ICASA. These will be set at <strong>the</strong> long run<strong>in</strong>cremental cost (LRIC) of build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a network by anefficient telecommunications provider, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g an average return oncapital. The <strong>in</strong>formation required for sett<strong>in</strong>g such rates, will be determ<strong>in</strong>edby <strong>the</strong> Chart of Accounts <strong>and</strong> Cost Allocation Manual (COA/CAM) that isobligatory for all network providers to submit.ICASA reserves <strong>the</strong> right to settle disputes over <strong>in</strong>terconnection <strong>and</strong> enforce<strong>the</strong> m<strong>in</strong>imum requirements established above for <strong>in</strong>terconnection agreements.Similar guidel<strong>in</strong>es have been established for facilities leas<strong>in</strong>g, ano<strong>the</strong>rimportant practice for fur<strong>the</strong>r<strong>in</strong>g competition <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> telecommunications<strong>in</strong>dustry.The number<strong>in</strong>g plan has yet to be f<strong>in</strong>alised by ICASA though a proposedpolicy document has been released which provides us with an <strong>in</strong>sight <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong>pr<strong>in</strong>ciples that ICASA is work<strong>in</strong>g with.For local access, <strong>the</strong> competition concerns revolve around number portability.Consumers face a cost of switch<strong>in</strong>g local access providers if <strong>the</strong>y have tochange <strong>the</strong>ir telephone number. This represents a barrier to entry <strong>and</strong> limitseffective competition from any new entrant. The switch<strong>in</strong>g costs <strong>in</strong>clude<strong>in</strong>form<strong>in</strong>g all associates of <strong>the</strong> change <strong>and</strong>, for bus<strong>in</strong>esses, adjust<strong>in</strong>g anyletterheads, bus<strong>in</strong>ess cards <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>formational material that has <strong>the</strong> number onit. These costs are significant enough to prevent numerous changes occurr<strong>in</strong>g<strong>and</strong> so <strong>in</strong>itially provide <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent with some market power. ICASA hasnot made a decision on this or provided any direction. The key problem is thatit does come with costs to <strong>the</strong> network provider because <strong>the</strong>ir networks needto be upgraded to operate number portability. ICASA is putt<strong>in</strong>g aside a blockof numbers <strong>in</strong> case number portability does not materialise <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> newentrant requires its own numbers.For long-distance network providers <strong>the</strong> preferred outcome is that a customercan pre-select a long-distance network provider <strong>and</strong> so <strong>the</strong>re is no need todial additional digits first. Aga<strong>in</strong>, ICASA has not made policy on this butsuggests that pre-selection “may be a requirement under <strong>the</strong> new regulatorystructure” (SATRA 1999). An <strong>in</strong>terim measure is to use as short as possible‘carrier access code’ until pre-selection is available. The recognition is that <strong>the</strong>shorter <strong>the</strong> access code, <strong>the</strong> less <strong>in</strong>convenience to customers <strong>and</strong> so <strong>the</strong> lessdiscrim<strong>in</strong>ation aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>the</strong> entrant. In order to allow consumers <strong>the</strong> flexibility toselect an alternative provider for <strong>in</strong>dividual calls, it is preferable to have preselectionoverride codes too. The issue of offer<strong>in</strong>g pre-selection concerns <strong>the</strong>upgrad<strong>in</strong>g of Telkom’s networks.For long-distance service providers who resale leased capacity, <strong>the</strong> accesscodes will be necessary. Ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se as short as possible is a means tomake <strong>the</strong>m more convenient to customers. If regulation allows serviceproviders to be pre-selected too, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>se would not be necessary.34


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>3.6 Public Interest ConsiderationsTwo important social objectives of telecommunications policy are universalservice <strong>and</strong> human resource development. These are given concrete support<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Act through <strong>the</strong> formation of two funds <strong>and</strong> a supervis<strong>in</strong>g agency foruniversal service.3.6.1 Universal ServiceThe Universal Service Agency (USA) has been established with <strong>the</strong> goal of<strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> recommend<strong>in</strong>g ways to achieve universal service. This<strong>in</strong>cludes def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g what <strong>the</strong> universal access or service targets are. TheAgency has two tools with which to <strong>in</strong>fluence universal service. First, <strong>the</strong>y mayrecommend licence conditions that help br<strong>in</strong>g about universal service/access.Currently, both <strong>the</strong> cellular network providers <strong>and</strong> Telkom have significantobligations to provide services to under-serviced areas, as discussed above.While <strong>the</strong>se conditions rema<strong>in</strong>, new entrants will be given similar conditions toensure no competitive advantage is given to <strong>the</strong>m.Second, <strong>the</strong> Universal Service Fund (USF) was established to subsidise"needy persons towards <strong>the</strong> cost of <strong>the</strong> provision to or <strong>the</strong> use by <strong>the</strong>m oftelecommunications services", <strong>and</strong> to repay Telkom <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r licence holderswith universal service obligations for extend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir services to poorly orunserviced areas <strong>and</strong> communities. For now, Telkom will receive most of <strong>the</strong>money as it rolls out to <strong>the</strong>se areas. The fees are non-discrim<strong>in</strong>atory <strong>and</strong> havebeen set by SATRA at 0.16% of turnover per annum for network providers,R1500 per annum for VANS <strong>and</strong> R1000 per annum for private networks.3.6.2 Human Resource DevelopmentThe Department of Communications will manage <strong>the</strong> Human Resources Fundwhose goal is to "promote <strong>the</strong> provision of adequately skilled humanresources at all levels of <strong>the</strong> telecommunications sector <strong>in</strong> sufficient numbers... <strong>in</strong> such a manner as to redress past unfair discrim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> education,tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> employment". The annual contributions to this fund are half thoseto <strong>the</strong> universal service fund <strong>and</strong> are similarly non-discrim<strong>in</strong>atory.The Act makes provision for a wide range of applications for which this Fundcan be used, from tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> schools through to postgraduates, from unskilledto artisans. The funds may be used for applications from bursaries toupgrad<strong>in</strong>g teach<strong>in</strong>g staff <strong>and</strong> facilities <strong>in</strong> selected <strong>in</strong>stitutions.35


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>4. Market Structure <strong>and</strong> Contestability Analysis<strong>Regulation</strong> has clearly shaped <strong>the</strong> domestic telecommunications market byrestrict<strong>in</strong>g competition <strong>in</strong> most services. The analysis of market structures is<strong>the</strong>refore relatively un<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g. What is more <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> most cases is<strong>the</strong> level of potential entry if <strong>the</strong> markets were opened to competition. Thisprovides some <strong>in</strong>dication of what might happen if free entry was allowed <strong>and</strong>so what regulatory safeguard measures might be required. This section looksat <strong>the</strong> different stages of production <strong>in</strong> telecommunications <strong>and</strong> provides <strong>in</strong>itialanalysis of relevant markets, market structure, <strong>and</strong> contestability. Thepurpose is to provide some guidance for strategic <strong>in</strong>terventions by <strong>the</strong><strong>Competition</strong> Commission <strong>and</strong> not to provide exact data on <strong>the</strong> state of <strong>the</strong>market <strong>and</strong> its performance. This is best done at <strong>the</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t of <strong>the</strong> competitioncompla<strong>in</strong>t as <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry is cont<strong>in</strong>ually chang<strong>in</strong>g. ICASA (Gazette Number:21925 General Notice Number: 4715) has a recent review of <strong>the</strong> PSTN prices<strong>and</strong> performance <strong>in</strong> recent years.4.1 Provision of Customer Premises Equipment (CPE)4.1.1 Relevant MarketsThe relevant market is <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>and</strong> not manufacture of CPE. With<strong>in</strong> thiscategory, <strong>the</strong> most obvious horizontal division of <strong>the</strong> market would be:• Fixed l<strong>in</strong>e telephones (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g fixed wireless which uses <strong>the</strong> samephone)• Mobile h<strong>and</strong>sets• PABXsIn terms of competition analysis, <strong>the</strong>re may be scope for more narrowdef<strong>in</strong>itions depend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> features of each piece of equipment. This wouldneed to come out <strong>in</strong> a specific enquiry.4.1.2 Market StructureThe market for supply<strong>in</strong>g (CPE) is fully liberalised with free entry.Fixed l<strong>in</strong>e telephonesThe ma<strong>in</strong> market players are retailers <strong>and</strong> Telkom. Telkom is likely to rema<strong>in</strong>a highly dom<strong>in</strong>ant supplier because <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent PSTN always reta<strong>in</strong>s anadvantage by be<strong>in</strong>g vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated with local access provision. Theadvantages may stem from:• customer convenience• a default situation whereby a phone is provided unless o<strong>the</strong>rwiserequested• ability to have <strong>the</strong> phone paid off over a longer period through <strong>in</strong>tegrationwith <strong>the</strong> customer bill<strong>in</strong>g system• customer database for promotional material36


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>In <strong>the</strong> UK, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent BT still had over 50% of <strong>the</strong> market after 10 years ofliberalisation.Mobile h<strong>and</strong>setsThere are likely to be no dom<strong>in</strong>ant players <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> provision of mobile h<strong>and</strong>sets.The crucial difference to fixed l<strong>in</strong>e is that <strong>the</strong> market for CPE supply wasliberal from <strong>the</strong> start <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> network providers were not <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>retail<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m. The service providers who did provide <strong>the</strong>m <strong>and</strong> who wouldhave some vertical <strong>in</strong>tegration advantage are sufficiently numerous not tohave market power.PABXsThis is likely to be a more competitive market than fixed l<strong>in</strong>e phones asbus<strong>in</strong>esses are likely to source directly from manufacturers.4.1.3 ContestabilityThe market for supply of CPE is an open one with no real barriers to entry.There are also a large number of firms <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market. However, <strong>the</strong>re areadvantages for vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated service providers (fixed or mobile) thatneed to be monitored. This problem may be particularly acute with fixed l<strong>in</strong>ewhere <strong>the</strong>re is only one service provider (Telkom) <strong>and</strong> a history of monopolysupply (so start<strong>in</strong>g at 100% coverage).4.2 Fixed Local Access4.2.1 Relevant MarketLocal access can be def<strong>in</strong>ed as a dist<strong>in</strong>ct market from long-distance. The keyquestion here is whe<strong>the</strong>r access through o<strong>the</strong>r technologies – specificallycable, fixed wireless <strong>and</strong> mobile – are suitable substitutes for fixed l<strong>in</strong>e PSTNto fall <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same relevant market. This is important as it will <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>the</strong>level of competition <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore some of <strong>the</strong> regulatorychoices made. All offer telephony <strong>and</strong> so it is tempt<strong>in</strong>g to def<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong>m all as <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> same market.In search of a more narrow def<strong>in</strong>ition, <strong>the</strong> most natural division of <strong>the</strong> marketwould be to separate fixed from mobile. In <strong>the</strong> fixed category would lie cable,fixed wireless <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> PSTN. On <strong>the</strong> surface <strong>the</strong>re appears to be a stronglevel of substitutability between <strong>the</strong> mobile <strong>and</strong> fixed <strong>in</strong> South Africa as manycustomers who do not have access to a fixed l<strong>in</strong>e have purchased cellular.However, it is important to recognise that <strong>the</strong>re are some crucial differencestoo.• cellular offers mobility for which fixed l<strong>in</strong>e is a poor substitute• fixed l<strong>in</strong>e has greater b<strong>and</strong>width (if purchased), permitt<strong>in</strong>g it to transfervideo <strong>and</strong> data faster than cellular• <strong>the</strong>re are differences <strong>in</strong> customer equipment present<strong>in</strong>g switch<strong>in</strong>g costs(though not significant)37


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>• on a common national pric<strong>in</strong>g system, cellular is more expensive thanfixed l<strong>in</strong>e access.• Many customers make use of both suggest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>y are not substitutes butcomplements• The two are regulated separately <strong>in</strong> most countries which suggests that<strong>the</strong>y are considered separate marketsAlso, <strong>the</strong> current level of substitutability may have been enhanced by twotemporary factors:• Excess dem<strong>and</strong> for telephony that existed when cellular operators werelicenced - excess dem<strong>and</strong> raises <strong>the</strong> effective price of fixed l<strong>in</strong>e for thosewithout access (because <strong>the</strong>y <strong>in</strong>corporate <strong>the</strong> cost of wait<strong>in</strong>g) mak<strong>in</strong>g ahigher priced cellular a closer substitute.• Public monopoly – Telkom is less efficient than many <strong>in</strong>ternational players<strong>in</strong> liberalised markets <strong>and</strong> may also be pursu<strong>in</strong>g monopoly pric<strong>in</strong>g. Thecomb<strong>in</strong>ation of possible <strong>in</strong>efficiency <strong>and</strong> monopoly pric<strong>in</strong>g means thatprices may be <strong>in</strong>flated mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m more substitutable with <strong>the</strong> moreexpensive mobile technology.It is difficult to determ<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> level of substitutability <strong>in</strong> South Africa issufficient to have mobile <strong>and</strong> fixed categorised <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same market. It is alsounclear whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> level of substitutability may actually decrease as soon asmore competition is <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong>to fixed l<strong>in</strong>e market <strong>and</strong> saturation of localaccess dem<strong>and</strong> is reached. What is clear is that <strong>the</strong>y are usually regulatedseparately <strong>and</strong> so considered separate markets. It may <strong>the</strong>refore be wise toadopt a more cautious narrow market def<strong>in</strong>ition for now, separat<strong>in</strong>g fixed l<strong>in</strong>elocal access from mobile.However, it is go<strong>in</strong>g to be important to review this periodically. In particular,given <strong>the</strong> more rapid rate of technological change <strong>in</strong> mobile, specificallyimpact<strong>in</strong>g on costs <strong>and</strong> b<strong>and</strong>width (UMTS), <strong>the</strong> market boundaries may wellchange <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> two considered sufficiently substitutable.The second case is to see if fixed access should be split fur<strong>the</strong>r. The division<strong>in</strong>to cable, fixed wireless <strong>and</strong> PSTN does not seem a suitable division as allare merely alternative means of delivery of what is essentially a fixed localaccess product. Regulatory practice also usually places <strong>the</strong>m <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> samemarket, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that this is <strong>the</strong> case. The one dimension on which todifferentiate may be b<strong>and</strong>width. However, for telephony this is not an issue, itis only an issue for VANS. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> PSTN can provide broadb<strong>and</strong> accessat a higher monthly rental fee. The conclusion would <strong>the</strong>refore suggest thatcable <strong>and</strong> fixed wireless should be <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same market <strong>and</strong> merelyconsidered different technological options but still offer<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> same service.The provision of local access can be split horizontally <strong>in</strong>to bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong>residential customers. The reason for this is <strong>the</strong> very different usage patterns<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> density of dem<strong>and</strong>. These serve to make bus<strong>in</strong>ess customers muchmore profitable, as <strong>the</strong>re are lower <strong>in</strong>stallation costs <strong>and</strong> higher usage ofcapacity.38


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>4.2.2 Market structureFixed local access is provided exclusively by Telkom. This exclusivity periodis due to end <strong>in</strong> May 2002, but with <strong>the</strong> option to extend for an additional yearif Telkom meets a certa<strong>in</strong> proportion of its proposed rollout to under-servicedareas <strong>and</strong> network performance targets by <strong>the</strong> end of 2001.4.2.3 ContestabilityThe primary barrier to entry is of course <strong>the</strong> regulated monopoly. A keyquestion for competition analysis is whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> deregulation of <strong>the</strong> sectorwould result <strong>in</strong> entry <strong>in</strong> South Africa. Entry can be def<strong>in</strong>ed as both complete(offer<strong>in</strong>g services to <strong>the</strong> entire market) or partial (servic<strong>in</strong>g only a componentof <strong>the</strong> market). This requires a focus on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r barriers to entry that exist <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> fixed local access market. The discussion of entry barriers also exam<strong>in</strong>eshow specific regulatory decisions may impact on <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> barrier facedby potential entrants.Entry Barriers• High sunk <strong>in</strong>frastructure costs – <strong>the</strong> high level of sunk costs (as discussed<strong>in</strong> section 1) are why local access is considered to be <strong>the</strong> only naturalmonopoly component <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> telecommunications production cha<strong>in</strong>. Theexcess capacity at <strong>the</strong> local access level also implies that it is sociallywasteful to duplicate resources, add<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> natural monopoly concerns.The high sunk costs imply low marg<strong>in</strong>al costs, allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbentspace to pursue a credible predatory pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy to deter entry.These costs can be reduced if <strong>the</strong> entrant has an exist<strong>in</strong>g localtransmission <strong>in</strong>frastructure that <strong>the</strong>y can ‘piggyback’ on. It is for this reasonthat <strong>the</strong> majority of entrants at <strong>the</strong> local level <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries are cableoperators who have <strong>in</strong>curred much of <strong>the</strong> fixed costs of putt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a localloop already. However, <strong>the</strong>re are currently no cable operators <strong>in</strong> SouthAfrica. Ano<strong>the</strong>r possibility is <strong>the</strong> fixed wireless approach where costs aremore closely related to traffic volumes <strong>and</strong> so less <strong>in</strong>vestment is required<strong>in</strong>itially. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>the</strong> regulator could grant an entrant permission to‘piggyback’ on <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent’s <strong>in</strong>frastructure (poles <strong>and</strong> ducts).An alternative strategy, <strong>and</strong> one be<strong>in</strong>g mooted by ICASA, is to grant as<strong>in</strong>gle entrant protection from fur<strong>the</strong>r competition <strong>in</strong> all sections of <strong>the</strong>market (<strong>in</strong>cl. long-distance) – i.e. licence a second national operator (SNO)only. The rationale is to provide <strong>the</strong> entrant with higher profits to<strong>in</strong>centivise <strong>the</strong>m to make <strong>the</strong> sunk <strong>in</strong>vestments. The problem with thisstrategy is that it usually favours <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent more than <strong>the</strong> entrant, as<strong>the</strong>y are <strong>the</strong> ones with a greater market share over which to makeabnormal profits. O<strong>the</strong>r problems <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> lack of <strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>the</strong>entrant to serve low-usage customers (result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a cherry-pick<strong>in</strong>gstrategy), <strong>and</strong> a questionable impact on long-term structural change <strong>and</strong>competition. This was <strong>the</strong> UK experience, with Mercury (<strong>the</strong> entrant)concentrat<strong>in</strong>g on bus<strong>in</strong>ess customers <strong>and</strong> selected households. In fact,Armstrong et al (1995:241) note of <strong>the</strong> British duopoly policy, “(t)hedeliberate restrictions on competition conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> duopoly policy,toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>in</strong>sufficient attention paid to overcom<strong>in</strong>g BTs <strong>in</strong>cumbency39


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>advantages, acted to preserve <strong>the</strong> essentially monopolistic character of<strong>the</strong> old system <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> core area of network operation”.• Customer switch<strong>in</strong>g costs – customer switch<strong>in</strong>g costs <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> cost ofchang<strong>in</strong>g numbers only, as equipment will have a common st<strong>and</strong>ard.Costs are usually considered higher for bus<strong>in</strong>ess than residential. Thesecosts are seen to be significant enough for customers not to switch often.Given <strong>the</strong> history of monopoly, switch<strong>in</strong>g costs are likely to provide <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent with a significant advantage. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, full number portability isunlikely to be granted by an <strong>in</strong>cumbent <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g marketpower <strong>and</strong> would need to be regulated. Armstrong et al (1995) note thatthis has proved important <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g cable providers to enter <strong>the</strong> localtelecommunications market <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK.• Interconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g – <strong>the</strong> reality of competition at <strong>the</strong> local access levelis that calls may orig<strong>in</strong>ate or term<strong>in</strong>ate at <strong>the</strong> competitor’s network. When acall is made from a subscriber of one network to a subscriber of ano<strong>the</strong>rnetwork, <strong>the</strong>n an <strong>in</strong>terconnection charge is imposed to route <strong>and</strong> term<strong>in</strong>ate<strong>the</strong> call. The implication is that <strong>in</strong>terconnection costs will have a significant<strong>in</strong>fluence on <strong>the</strong> price of calls for both networks. This applies equally to<strong>in</strong>terconnection charges with foreign networks <strong>and</strong> with domestic mobilenetworks. The key issue is whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>in</strong>terconnection canaffect <strong>the</strong> ability of a competitor to compete <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market. Clearly, if<strong>in</strong>terconnection affects <strong>the</strong> price of <strong>the</strong>ir product, <strong>the</strong>n it must be able toaffect <strong>the</strong>ir competitiveness. There are two possible scenarios that allfavour <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent.First, a common <strong>in</strong>terconnection price is agreed. In this case it wouldfavour <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent to overprice <strong>in</strong>terconnection. The reason is simple.The primary problem faced by an entrant is that on balance <strong>the</strong>re will bemore traffic term<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g at <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent’s network than on <strong>the</strong>ir own, dueto <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent has more subscribers. High <strong>in</strong>terconnectioncharges will <strong>the</strong>refore affect a far greater amount of calls made bysubscribers of <strong>the</strong> entrant, than those subscribers of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent. Theresult is a higher average price for local calls for <strong>the</strong> entrant relative to <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent.Second, an <strong>in</strong>terconnection price for each network is negotiated. The<strong>in</strong>cumbent aga<strong>in</strong> has far greater market power <strong>and</strong> so will be able to usethis to get better terms out of <strong>the</strong> entrant than <strong>the</strong>y are will<strong>in</strong>g to offer<strong>the</strong>mselves. Aga<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> result is higher average call costs for <strong>the</strong> entrant’ssubscribers.Ano<strong>the</strong>r strategy for <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent would be to delay <strong>the</strong> reach<strong>in</strong>g of anagreement, which would prevent <strong>the</strong> entrant from launch<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir service.Although <strong>the</strong> ICASA rules would <strong>the</strong>n call on <strong>the</strong> regulator to break <strong>the</strong>deadlock, <strong>the</strong> decision on what <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terconnection level would be couldensure fur<strong>the</strong>r delays. These time delays would impose heavy costs on <strong>the</strong>entrant.<strong>Regulation</strong> can overcome <strong>the</strong>se problems to an extent by stipulat<strong>in</strong>g alevel of <strong>in</strong>terconnection charges that come <strong>in</strong>to effect if better terms cannotbe negotiated. This lowers <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive for <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent to delay40


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>proceed<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> ensures that fur<strong>the</strong>r regulatory delays do not occur if nonegotiated terms are agreed. The problem is estimat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>terconnection rate. The nature of network <strong>in</strong>dustries is that many costsare common costs <strong>and</strong> so <strong>the</strong>re is discretion <strong>in</strong> how <strong>the</strong>y are allocated. It is<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terests of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent to allocate as much of its costs to <strong>the</strong>service where <strong>the</strong>y expect <strong>the</strong> least competition, <strong>and</strong> where <strong>the</strong>y are ableto negatively <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>the</strong> price of <strong>the</strong>ir competitors <strong>the</strong> most. This is ofcourse local access. The <strong>in</strong>cumbent is <strong>the</strong>refore likely to try pass off asmuch of <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>in</strong>to local access to justify high <strong>in</strong>terconnection pricesthat penalise both o<strong>the</strong>r local access providers <strong>and</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r services that<strong>in</strong>terconnect (long-distance, VANS, mobile).Interconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g can also be used to compensate for o<strong>the</strong>r<strong>in</strong>cumbency advantages to facilitate entry. The usual strategy is to force<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent to offer <strong>in</strong>terconnection rates that are below cost to provide<strong>the</strong> entrant with some advantage of <strong>the</strong>ir own. Ei<strong>the</strong>r way, failure to resolve<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terconnection issue satisfatorily will result <strong>in</strong> greater uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty forpotential entrants <strong>in</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r services as local access is <strong>the</strong> essentialfacility <strong>in</strong> telecommunications. Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty can only lead to lower<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>centives, especially when <strong>the</strong>re are high sunk costs.• Current network coverage <strong>and</strong> universal service subsidies – given highsunk costs <strong>and</strong> customer switch<strong>in</strong>g costs, <strong>the</strong>re are low <strong>in</strong>centives to enterdirectly <strong>in</strong>to competition with <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent where <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent has alocal loop <strong>in</strong> place. The exception to this is high usage customers(especially long distance usage) that have high density – i.e. bus<strong>in</strong>esscustomers. However, for lower usage customers, <strong>the</strong> entrant may havemore <strong>in</strong>centive to enter areas that are not currently served by <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent. The exception would be areas that are not serviced because<strong>the</strong>ir usage is very low (usually poor households) <strong>and</strong>/or where <strong>in</strong>stallationcosts are very high per subscriber (i.e. rural areas). This can be overcomeif <strong>the</strong> entrant has access to <strong>the</strong> universal service subsidy to part fund <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>stallation of local loops <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se areas.If <strong>the</strong> unserviced areas are a large part of <strong>the</strong> market, <strong>the</strong>n access touniversal service subsidies <strong>and</strong> rapid entry <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> market are important <strong>in</strong>establish<strong>in</strong>g a viable local access base for <strong>the</strong> entrant. <strong>Regulation</strong> can helpby favour<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> entrant <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> provision of universal service subsidies <strong>and</strong>servic<strong>in</strong>g new property developments.Likelihood of EntryThe high barriers to entry at <strong>the</strong> local access level have made this <strong>the</strong> last‘natural monopoly’ component of <strong>the</strong> telecommunications system. Entry thathas occurred <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries has tended to be <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess componentof <strong>the</strong> market as high usage <strong>and</strong> density serve to lower <strong>in</strong>stallation costs, <strong>and</strong>allow <strong>in</strong>vestments to be written off quickly. Their high use of long-distanceservices provides <strong>the</strong> capacity to make <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> more lucrative longdistancemarket. Entry takes <strong>the</strong> form of establish<strong>in</strong>g long-distance networks<strong>and</strong> local bypass of <strong>the</strong> PSTN to <strong>the</strong>se networks.<strong>Competition</strong> that has emerged <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> residential component of <strong>the</strong> market hasgenerally been from cable companies us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir economies of scope. As41


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>South Africa does not have a cable TV operator, this is not a source of entrynow. It is also unlikely to be <strong>the</strong> case <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> future, as a cable TV companywould only be <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> a small group of high <strong>in</strong>come earners, plus <strong>the</strong>choice of technology for pay TV <strong>in</strong> South Africa is satellite (Multichoice <strong>and</strong>Sentech). The low teledensity <strong>in</strong> South Africa suggests that <strong>the</strong> entrant maybe tempted by <strong>the</strong> number of unserviced areas. However, <strong>the</strong> reality is that<strong>the</strong>y are unserviced because <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>the</strong> least viable group of potentialsubscribers. Therefore, unless <strong>the</strong> universal service fund<strong>in</strong>g was sufficient tomake <strong>the</strong>se customers profitable, <strong>the</strong>y are unlikely to be served by <strong>the</strong>entrant. Clearly entry at <strong>the</strong> residential level is unlikely to be significant unless<strong>the</strong>re is significant <strong>in</strong>centives from <strong>the</strong> regulator for entry, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g putt<strong>in</strong>grollout conditions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> licence, provid<strong>in</strong>g access to universal servicesubsidies, hav<strong>in</strong>g favourable <strong>in</strong>terconnection agreements <strong>and</strong> possiblylower<strong>in</strong>g competition <strong>in</strong> long-distance through a duopoly policy to allow <strong>the</strong>mto cross-subsidise services. Ei<strong>the</strong>r way, <strong>the</strong> entrant is unlikely to get asignificant share of <strong>the</strong> local access market to act as a discipl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g effect on<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent. Rate regulation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent will be <strong>the</strong> primary tool forensur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> protection of consumers aga<strong>in</strong>st abuse of dom<strong>in</strong>ance.4.3 Long Distance4.3.1 Relevant MarketThe long distance market can be separated <strong>in</strong>to national <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationalnetworks. It is also possible to talk of network providers <strong>and</strong> service providers<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> long-distance market (unlike <strong>the</strong> local access market). There is littlereason for separat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> market <strong>in</strong> any o<strong>the</strong>r way, as most long-distancenetworks are now fibre-optic <strong>and</strong> so can carry voice, data <strong>and</strong> broadcastquality. Choice of technology also matters less.4.3.2 Market structureThe network <strong>in</strong>frastructure for long distance is predom<strong>in</strong>ately owned byTelkom, but o<strong>the</strong>r network providers exist. In <strong>the</strong> national long distancemarket, Transtel <strong>and</strong> Esitel (<strong>the</strong> telecommunications arms of Transnet <strong>and</strong>Eskom), have considerable long-distance <strong>in</strong>frastructure that is used for privatepurposes <strong>and</strong> which Telkom can lease capacity for public purposes. Thisprivate network exists for historical reasons. In <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational long-distancemarket, <strong>the</strong>re are a large number of <strong>in</strong>ternational players that operate fibreoptic <strong>and</strong> satellite facilities that cover South Africa. They exist because <strong>the</strong>ir<strong>in</strong>frastructure is not located on South African soil <strong>and</strong> so cannot be regulated.Sentech holds capacity <strong>in</strong> satellite broadcast<strong>in</strong>g services.Despite o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>frastructure providers exist<strong>in</strong>g, Telkom has exclusive rights tooperate a long-distance network <strong>in</strong> South Africa. Therefore <strong>the</strong>se companiesare forced to lease to Telkom who <strong>the</strong>n provides <strong>the</strong> public service. TheTelkom monopoly means that <strong>the</strong> prices of all o<strong>the</strong>r services that use longdistancenetworks (mobile, Internet, VANS) are determ<strong>in</strong>ed by Telkom. If thismarket structure leads to cost <strong>in</strong>efficiencies, under<strong>in</strong>vestment or monopolypric<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> impact affects <strong>the</strong> full range of telecommunications products.42


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>4.3.3 ContestabilityThe primary barrier to entry for network <strong>and</strong> service provision is of course <strong>the</strong>regulated monopoly. Aga<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> key question is how will <strong>the</strong> market change ifentry was liberalised. In answer<strong>in</strong>g this question for long-distance, it isimportant to separate <strong>the</strong> network provision from <strong>the</strong> service provision, as <strong>the</strong>barriers to entry are considerably different. Entry can also be partial orcomplete. Partial may <strong>in</strong>clude bus<strong>in</strong>ess or metropolitan areas only, whilecomplete would <strong>in</strong>clude a national service.Barriers to entryThe barriers to entry for network providers <strong>in</strong>clude:• Sunk costs – <strong>the</strong> long distance network has fewer sunk costs to a full localaccess network. In addition, long distance is not considered a naturalmonopoly because excess capacity is not a problem. The collect<strong>in</strong>g oflocal traffic <strong>and</strong> funnell<strong>in</strong>g it down a s<strong>in</strong>gle long distance network ensureshigher capacity utilisation <strong>and</strong> scope for more than one network toprofitably exist.The level of sunk costs for long-distance networks can be more easilylowered than <strong>in</strong> local access. First, <strong>the</strong>re are more established networksdeliver<strong>in</strong>g o<strong>the</strong>r services mak<strong>in</strong>g economies of scope possible (<strong>in</strong>cluderailway, electricity). Also, satellite is a viable alternative to fixed l<strong>in</strong>e givenhigh capacity utilisation rates. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> South Africa <strong>the</strong>re exist privatenetworks with a national long-distance network already <strong>in</strong>stalled that hasspare capacity. The <strong>in</strong>cremental cost of provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> service to localaccess subscribers <strong>in</strong>volves provid<strong>in</strong>g a po<strong>in</strong>t-of-presence (PoP) switch<strong>and</strong> extend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> network to areas that are not covered yet.The sunk costs can be lowered for <strong>in</strong>itial entry if <strong>the</strong> entrant is able to leasecapacity from <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent on entry while <strong>the</strong>y roll out a more completenetwork (those that <strong>in</strong>tend gett<strong>in</strong>g a full network). This is <strong>the</strong> equivalentissue to allow a new mobile network operator to roam on exist<strong>in</strong>g networksdur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> rollout period.• Customer switch<strong>in</strong>g costs – customer switch<strong>in</strong>g costs between longdistance networks are focused on <strong>the</strong> diall<strong>in</strong>g process. If <strong>the</strong>re are morethan one long-distance providers, <strong>the</strong>n it is necessary for <strong>the</strong> subscriber tomake <strong>the</strong> choice. Given that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent is go<strong>in</strong>g to be <strong>the</strong> naturaldefault if no specific choice is made (because <strong>the</strong>y own <strong>the</strong> local accessnetwork), this offers <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent a dist<strong>in</strong>ct advantage over compet<strong>in</strong>gnetworks. The worst possible scenario is if <strong>the</strong> customer has an <strong>in</strong>cumbentdefault <strong>and</strong> needs to tap <strong>in</strong> an access code to use a compet<strong>in</strong>g longdistance provider. The longer this code is, <strong>the</strong> higher are <strong>the</strong> switch<strong>in</strong>gcosts.The least distortionary means is to have <strong>the</strong> customer pre-select <strong>the</strong> longdistanceprovider of choice <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n any long-distance call without anaccess code will be routed through <strong>the</strong>ir network of choice. If <strong>the</strong>subscriber wishes to override <strong>the</strong>ir selection, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> access code can beused. However, it is preferable that as short as possible access code isused to limit switch<strong>in</strong>g costs.43


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>• Interconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g – a long distance call must orig<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>and</strong> term<strong>in</strong>ate<strong>in</strong> a local access network. As such, <strong>the</strong> cost of <strong>in</strong>terconnection will impacton <strong>the</strong> overall cost of <strong>the</strong> long-distance call. Unless <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent isvertically separated (as with AT&T), <strong>the</strong>re is a danger that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbentcan set <strong>in</strong>terconnection rates at higher levels for compet<strong>in</strong>g long-distancenetworks <strong>and</strong> so raise <strong>the</strong> costs of <strong>the</strong>ir rivals. As discussed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> localaccess section, <strong>the</strong>re are also dangers of delay<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terconnectionagreements to raise rivals costs. The o<strong>the</strong>r danger with <strong>in</strong>terconnection isthat <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent offers a lower quality of connection to compet<strong>in</strong>g longdistanceproviders, mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir service less attractive to subscribers.• Facilities leas<strong>in</strong>g – as with <strong>in</strong>terconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong> price at whichfacilities are leased will <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>the</strong> price of rival’s costs. If <strong>the</strong> entrantneeds to lease facilities as a short-term measure, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> price of leas<strong>in</strong>gwill be an important <strong>in</strong>fluence on average costs. It is clearly <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terestof <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent to overprice <strong>the</strong>se services. The preferable arrangementis for <strong>the</strong> leas<strong>in</strong>g price to at least reflect long run costs of provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>facilities. However, it is also feasible that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent price below cost <strong>in</strong>off-peak periods to get rid of excess capacity.For long-distance service providers <strong>the</strong> barriers to entry are substantially less.Service providers lease network capacity from network providers <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>nresell it to subscribers on a per m<strong>in</strong>ute basis. The <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>the</strong>y require isa bill<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>and</strong> a switch connection to <strong>the</strong> long distance provider’s po<strong>in</strong>tof-presence(<strong>the</strong>y are routed through <strong>the</strong> local access network like all o<strong>the</strong>rs).However, service provider’s face <strong>the</strong> same customer switch<strong>in</strong>g costs ascompet<strong>in</strong>g network providers. In liberated markets <strong>the</strong> pre-select option israrely made available to service providers because of <strong>the</strong> highly contestablenature <strong>and</strong> proliferation of suppliers. Service providers also face <strong>the</strong> problemof <strong>in</strong>terconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> facilities leas<strong>in</strong>g. The facilities leas<strong>in</strong>g is more ofa problem for service providers than network providers because <strong>the</strong>y lease allfacilities <strong>and</strong> not just where <strong>the</strong>y have not rolled out.Likelihood of entryEntry <strong>in</strong>to long distance network <strong>and</strong> service provision is highly likely <strong>in</strong> SouthAfrica if <strong>the</strong> market were liberalised. On <strong>the</strong> network side, Transtel <strong>and</strong> Esitelalready have networks <strong>in</strong> place, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational network providers alreadyexist but cannot sell directly to <strong>the</strong> subscriber. Given <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>in</strong> data traffic,<strong>the</strong>re is considerable scope for o<strong>the</strong>r entrants <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> market. Open<strong>in</strong>g resale<strong>and</strong> network competition at <strong>the</strong> same time makes it highly likely that <strong>in</strong>itialcompetitors will lease facilities while <strong>the</strong>y establish <strong>the</strong>ir own networks. Thiswill accelerate <strong>the</strong> process of competition. <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>in</strong> service provision iseven more likely given <strong>the</strong> low costs of entry. However, <strong>the</strong> regulatorydecisions around facilities leas<strong>in</strong>g, customer switch<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terconnectioncosts will have a considerable impact on <strong>the</strong> entry of firms <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> coverageof <strong>the</strong>ir networks.44


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>4.4 Mobile4.4.1 Relevant MarketThe discussion of <strong>the</strong> relevant market <strong>in</strong> fixed local access determ<strong>in</strong>ed thatmobile access was not a substitute for fixed local access, though it may beconsidered as such <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> near future. Also on <strong>the</strong> horizon are <strong>the</strong> so-called3 rd generation cellular services (UMTS). These can be separated from <strong>the</strong>current 2 nd generation GSM networks <strong>in</strong> that <strong>the</strong>y have broadb<strong>and</strong> capacity<strong>and</strong> so are able to provide a range of product options that <strong>the</strong> GSM networkscannot. Although <strong>the</strong>se can be seen as two dist<strong>in</strong>ct markets, <strong>the</strong>re areeconomies of scope <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir production. F<strong>in</strong>ally, network provision can beseparated from service provision.4.4.2 Market structureThere are currently two network providers, MTN <strong>and</strong> Vodacom, with a thirdnetwork licence currently be<strong>in</strong>g issued to Cell C (pend<strong>in</strong>g litigation). Themajority shareholder <strong>in</strong> MTN is M-Cell <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> Vodacom is Vodafone <strong>and</strong>Telkom (50%). The large sharehold<strong>in</strong>g of Telkom is potentially a cause forconcern, especially as mobile is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly becom<strong>in</strong>g a substitute for fixedlocal access. This sharehold<strong>in</strong>g gives Telkom <strong>the</strong> chance to act strategicallyto <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>the</strong> degree of substitutability <strong>and</strong> transfer price betweencompetitive <strong>and</strong> uncompetitive markets. The market shares have stabilised ataround 61% for Vodacom <strong>and</strong> 39% for MTN (Telkom 2001). Given that <strong>the</strong>market has grown at almost 50% per annum, <strong>the</strong> primary concern of bothnetwork providers is sign<strong>in</strong>g up subscribers, <strong>and</strong> not compet<strong>in</strong>g on price tow<strong>in</strong> subscribers away from <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r network. Recent estimates are that if CellC entered <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry at this po<strong>in</strong>t, <strong>the</strong>y would only secure a 10% share of<strong>the</strong> market by 2003 (Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Report 19 February 2001). The<strong>Telecommunications</strong> Act requires <strong>the</strong> regulator to exam<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r a fourthlicence is desirable or not.The network operators do not deal directly with <strong>the</strong> public but wholesaleairtime to appo<strong>in</strong>ted service providers who <strong>in</strong> turn retail network access to <strong>the</strong>public or corporations us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir own tariff structures. The service providerscurrently appo<strong>in</strong>ted to each network are:• MTN network – Autopage Cellular, M-Tel, Nashua, Nedtel, PlesseyCellular, Radiospoor Cellular, Sebcom, Supercall, Transtel <strong>and</strong> TTC.• Vodacom network – Afritel, Autopage Cellular, Cellphones Direct, GSMCellular, Nashua, Nedtel, Plessey Cellular, Radiospoor Cellular, Supercall,Teljoy <strong>and</strong> Vodac4.4.3 ContestabilityThe primary barrier to entry for network provision is regulation – <strong>the</strong> need for alicence (currently restricted to three). In service provision <strong>the</strong>re is lessregulatory <strong>in</strong>tervention but service providers need to be approved by <strong>the</strong>network providers for reasons of protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir reputation <strong>and</strong> customerservice levels.45


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Aga<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> key question is how will <strong>the</strong> market change if entry was liberalised.In answer<strong>in</strong>g this question for mobile, it is important to separate <strong>the</strong> networkprovision from <strong>the</strong> service provision, as <strong>the</strong> barriers to entry are considerablydifferent.Barriers to entryIn <strong>the</strong> network component <strong>the</strong> barriers to entry <strong>in</strong>clude:• Sunk costs – if <strong>the</strong> network provider is required to roll out a completenationwide network (as is <strong>the</strong> case <strong>in</strong> South Africa), <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> sunk costswill clearly be high. However, with mobile, as opposed to fixed l<strong>in</strong>e, <strong>the</strong>level of <strong>in</strong>frastructure required depends on <strong>the</strong> level of traffic (see section1). The result is that <strong>the</strong>re is a lower <strong>in</strong>vestment required to launch aservice, but which can rise <strong>in</strong> proportion to <strong>the</strong> growth <strong>in</strong> subscribers. Thismakes entry easier <strong>and</strong> more likely that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry can support morethan one or two network providers. A fur<strong>the</strong>r means of eas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> entry ofa new network is to allow <strong>the</strong> use of <strong>in</strong>frastructure from compet<strong>in</strong>g networkproviders until a full network is up <strong>and</strong> runn<strong>in</strong>g. The reduction <strong>in</strong> time toenlist subscribers means that <strong>the</strong> entrant can start generat<strong>in</strong>g a return on<strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>vestment sooner, <strong>the</strong>reby lower<strong>in</strong>g costs of establishment.• Interconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g – as with any network, a mobile network needs toconnect to all o<strong>the</strong>r networks <strong>in</strong> order to provide <strong>the</strong>ir subscribers with <strong>the</strong>chance to call anyone else. The key <strong>in</strong>terconnection prices are fixed localaccess, o<strong>the</strong>r mobile networks <strong>and</strong> long-distance. There are similarconcerns about overpric<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>in</strong>terconnection, especially when <strong>the</strong>re is adom<strong>in</strong>ant player <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> mobile networks or a player that isvertically/horizontally <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>to o<strong>the</strong>r markets (long-distance or localaccess). The dom<strong>in</strong>ant player concerns were discussed <strong>in</strong> detail underlocal access. Problems are non-st<strong>and</strong>ard pric<strong>in</strong>g, delay<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terconnection,or overpric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terconnection. For <strong>the</strong> vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated/horizontally<strong>in</strong>tegrated firm <strong>the</strong>re are opportunities to engage <strong>in</strong> transfer pric<strong>in</strong>g from<strong>the</strong> competitive segment to <strong>the</strong> uncompetitive segment. If <strong>the</strong>re is a localaccess monopoly with a mobile network, it may be <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>terests toraise local access <strong>in</strong>terconnection prices for all mobile networks (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong>ir own). There is no fear of retaliation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> local access market where<strong>the</strong>re is no competition, <strong>and</strong> overpric<strong>in</strong>g enables <strong>the</strong>m to extract rents fromo<strong>the</strong>r mobile providers <strong>and</strong> also affect <strong>the</strong> overall substitutability of mobilewith fixed l<strong>in</strong>e.• Facilities leas<strong>in</strong>g – similar concerns to <strong>in</strong>terconnection arise on facilitiesleas<strong>in</strong>g. The difference is merely <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> contract, but <strong>the</strong>problems of strategic pric<strong>in</strong>g of facilities rema<strong>in</strong>s <strong>the</strong> same.• Customer switch<strong>in</strong>g – customer switch<strong>in</strong>g costs <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> usual numberswitch<strong>in</strong>g issues, but also would <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> use of long-term contracts by<strong>the</strong> current service providers (l<strong>in</strong>ked to specific network providers). Longtermcontracts are part of <strong>the</strong> product range offered by service providers(<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g pay-as-you-go) <strong>and</strong> serve <strong>the</strong> customer by provid<strong>in</strong>g a chanceto ‘hire’ a phone as part of <strong>the</strong> contract – <strong>the</strong>reby sav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m from <strong>the</strong>purchase price. However, <strong>the</strong> length of contracts would need to be46


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>exam<strong>in</strong>ed more closely to see whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y constitute significant barriersor not.The entry of service providers is far easier. The sunk costs <strong>in</strong>clude a retailnetwork <strong>and</strong> customer bill<strong>in</strong>g system. However, <strong>the</strong>y also need to beapproved by <strong>the</strong> network providers so some quality assurance is required.This is justifiable on bus<strong>in</strong>ess grounds. Only if <strong>the</strong> network provider hasvested <strong>in</strong>terests <strong>in</strong> ano<strong>the</strong>r service provider, is <strong>the</strong>re a potential cause forconcern around discrim<strong>in</strong>atory behaviour to favour <strong>the</strong>ir service provider.Likelihood of entryThe lower <strong>in</strong>itial sunk costs <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> mobile network establishment meansthat <strong>the</strong> market is able to susta<strong>in</strong> far more network operators. The existence ofscale economies does mean that a limited number of competitors will exist,especially if <strong>the</strong>y are limited to provide a national service. The level ofcompetition is likely to be fiercer <strong>in</strong> mobile networks because <strong>the</strong>re was no<strong>in</strong>itial monopoly.4.5 Value-added Network Services (VANS)4.5.1 Relevant marketsThe VANS sector can be separated from basic voice. The sector comprises ofa number of potential horizontal markets that will receive greater clarity <strong>in</strong>specific compla<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestigation. The market can be split roughly <strong>in</strong>topublic data services (Internet provision) <strong>and</strong> private data services. Each of<strong>the</strong>se may be fur<strong>the</strong>r sub-divided. For <strong>in</strong>stance, it may be possible to subdivideInternet based on access mode. Currently, Internet content <strong>and</strong>services delivered to mobile phones differ from that delivered to PCs on fixedl<strong>in</strong>es. The key difference is <strong>the</strong> smaller screen <strong>and</strong> no broadb<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> so <strong>the</strong>services are more limited. Although 3G cellular will br<strong>in</strong>g broadb<strong>and</strong>, it will stillreta<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> small screen <strong>and</strong> so this market division may persist. It may also bepossible to separate fixed l<strong>in</strong>e access <strong>in</strong>to dial-up <strong>and</strong> leased l<strong>in</strong>e access.Vertical divisions could <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> separation of customer management fromnetwork management (core backbone). However, <strong>in</strong> relation to generaltelecommunications regulation, <strong>the</strong> markets can be considered as one.4.5.2 Market structurePublic data networks (Internet)Internet access <strong>in</strong>cludes both leased l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> dial-up access. South Africaranks 25th <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> world <strong>in</strong> terms of number of Internet sites. There are anestimated 2.5 million Internet users <strong>in</strong> South Africa (media africa.com 2000).Telkom provides <strong>the</strong> physical <strong>in</strong>frastructure backbone for Internet as <strong>the</strong>yhave a monopoly over this component. The leased networks are <strong>the</strong>nmanaged by various companies <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g The Internet solution, Pipex InternetAfrica, Spr<strong>in</strong>t SA, SAIX, OpenNet, <strong>and</strong> UUNet. Of <strong>the</strong>se, SAIX (Telkomowned)offers a full <strong>in</strong>frastructure for Internet service providers (ISPs),allow<strong>in</strong>g even small niche players to establish <strong>and</strong> run an ISP without<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> actual po<strong>in</strong>ts-of-presence (PoPs) to connect to <strong>the</strong> local switch.47


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>There are also a large number of service providers who lease capacity from<strong>the</strong> networks <strong>and</strong> retail to <strong>the</strong> public at <strong>the</strong>ir own tariffs. There are currentlyover 100 Internet Service Providers (ISPs) <strong>in</strong> South Africa, of vary<strong>in</strong>g size. At<strong>the</strong> end of 2000 <strong>the</strong>re were a few large ISPs - M-web, Worldonl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> Xs<strong>in</strong>et<strong>in</strong> dialup access, <strong>and</strong> Internet Solution <strong>in</strong> leased l<strong>in</strong>e access. The difficulty <strong>in</strong>determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g market structure <strong>in</strong> this sector is that <strong>the</strong> market changesdramatically each year. The most recent development has been <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>troduction of Absa freemail that is apparently sign<strong>in</strong>g users at a rate of 8000per week (Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Report March 2001).Private data servicesThe <strong>in</strong>dustry was launched when VANS service provider licences were issued<strong>in</strong> 1991. There are currently about 60 license holders with approximately 12000 customers <strong>and</strong> a total annual revenue of around R180-200 million. Thetop three service providers have a market share of 75% <strong>and</strong> are Trafix,EDS/Vanco <strong>and</strong> FirstNet. O<strong>the</strong>r significant networks <strong>in</strong>clude GOVNET, InfoVan, <strong>and</strong> Denel Informatics.4.5.3 ContestabilityThe VANS market has scale economies <strong>and</strong> sunk costs but not on a scalenear that of a PSTN or mobile network. This makes it a relatively contestablemarket, reflected <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> greater number of market players. The key positionthat Telkom holds as <strong>the</strong> only provider of l<strong>in</strong>es to all <strong>the</strong>se operations, raisesconcerns over whe<strong>the</strong>r it is favour<strong>in</strong>g its own companies <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se markets.There is also scope for strategic behaviour from o<strong>the</strong>r players <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market as<strong>the</strong>y exploit customer switch<strong>in</strong>g costs or market power.4.6 O<strong>the</strong>r Mobile Services4.6.1 Relevant MarketsBefore <strong>the</strong> arrival of mobile telephony, a range of o<strong>the</strong>r mobile servicesexisted. Most important are pag<strong>in</strong>g, radio trunk<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> wireless data services.Unfortunately for <strong>the</strong> operators of <strong>the</strong>se services, <strong>the</strong> launch of mobiletelephony has cut deeply <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong>ir market. The reason is that mobiletelephony has an exp<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g range of service products beyond basic voice arevery close substitutes to <strong>the</strong>se o<strong>the</strong>r mobile service products. Cellular phonesoffer pag<strong>in</strong>g style services (SMS, <strong>in</strong>formational services), radio trunk<strong>in</strong>g (longdistance radio communications) <strong>and</strong> wireless data (email <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>glyInternet). The result is that <strong>the</strong>se sectors have stagnated.4.6.2 Market StructureThe discussion focuses on <strong>the</strong> companies specialised <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se products.However, competition can be seen to <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> mobile networks.Pag<strong>in</strong>g SectorThe pag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry was <strong>the</strong> first to have private operators issued licences<strong>and</strong> is well established <strong>in</strong> South Africa. In 1999 <strong>the</strong>re were 21 pag<strong>in</strong>gcompanies with an estimated market of 110 000 pagers <strong>and</strong> revenue of R12148


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>million. The dom<strong>in</strong>ant operators are Radiospoor (40%), Autopage (25%),Pag<strong>in</strong>g Plus (10%). A h<strong>and</strong>ful of <strong>the</strong>se operators do not provide services to<strong>the</strong> public but operate <strong>the</strong>ir private corporate pag<strong>in</strong>g services only.Radio Trunk<strong>in</strong>gThe first radio trunk<strong>in</strong>g licences <strong>in</strong> South Africa were only issued <strong>in</strong> 1993, ayear before <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of cellular networks. The expansion of <strong>the</strong> cellularnetworks has stunted <strong>the</strong> growth of radio trunk<strong>in</strong>g as <strong>the</strong>y are directcompetitors <strong>in</strong> mobile communications services. There are currently 11licensed operators shar<strong>in</strong>g a market of between 5000 <strong>and</strong> 7000 radios. Thesector is relatively small with revenues of R9 – R12.5 million per annum. Thesector is dom<strong>in</strong>ated by 3 operators – Fleetcall, Q-Trunk <strong>and</strong> One-to-One.Wireless Data ServicesThere are currently only 2 wireless data network providers, Swiftnet <strong>and</strong> WBS.4.6.3 ContestabilityAs with VANS, entry barriers are low to <strong>the</strong>se mobile offer<strong>in</strong>gs. The fact that<strong>the</strong> same services are feasible over <strong>the</strong> cellular networks make this a highlycontested market.49


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>5. Regulatory issues for <strong>the</strong> SA telecommunications<strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir potential efficiency/public <strong>in</strong>terestimpactThe current regulatory regime <strong>in</strong> telecommunications has to change by <strong>the</strong>end of 2003 <strong>in</strong> compliance with South Africa’s commitment to <strong>the</strong> WTO. Indecid<strong>in</strong>g how <strong>the</strong> regulatory regime will change, one needs to take account of<strong>the</strong> range of objectives laid out for telecommunications policy <strong>and</strong> not justfocus on regulat<strong>in</strong>g for efficiency only. The full list of objectives werediscussed <strong>in</strong> section 3, but are repeated here. They <strong>in</strong>clude• promote <strong>the</strong> universal <strong>and</strong> affordable provision of telecommunicationservices;• ensure that, <strong>in</strong> relation to <strong>the</strong> provision of telecommunication services, <strong>the</strong>needs of <strong>the</strong> local communities <strong>and</strong> areas are duly taken <strong>in</strong>to account;• encourage ownership <strong>and</strong> control of telecommunication services bypersons from historically disadvantaged groups;• encourage <strong>the</strong> development of human resources <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry;• promote small, medium <strong>and</strong> micro-enterprises with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry;• promote <strong>the</strong> provision of a wide range of telecommunication services <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest of <strong>the</strong> economic growth <strong>and</strong> development of <strong>the</strong> Republic;• encourage <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry;• encourage <strong>the</strong> development of a competitive <strong>and</strong> effectivetelecommunications manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> supply sector;• ensure fair competition with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry;• ensure efficient use of <strong>the</strong> radio frequency spectrum;There is no specific priority order<strong>in</strong>g of objectives <strong>and</strong> different <strong>in</strong>terest groupswill rank <strong>the</strong>m differently. The regulatory outcome will depend on <strong>the</strong>barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g process amongst <strong>the</strong> different <strong>in</strong>terest groups.This section exam<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> various regulatory options on <strong>the</strong> table. Ra<strong>the</strong>r thanput down various possible models, <strong>the</strong> discussion is structured around fourcritical components of <strong>the</strong> regulatory regime – namely structure, entry, pric<strong>in</strong>g<strong>and</strong> quality. The <strong>in</strong>terconnection between policies on each component will bemade clear.5.1 StructureThe key structural questions <strong>in</strong> telecommunications deregulation are:• Whe<strong>the</strong>r to separate <strong>the</strong> natural monopoly component (or essentialfacilities) – fixed local access – from <strong>the</strong> parts of <strong>the</strong> networks that offerpotential for competition – CPE supply, long distance (vertical separation)• Whe<strong>the</strong>r network provision as a whole should be separated from serviceprovision - VANS or even basic voice (vertical separation)50


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>• Whe<strong>the</strong>r mobile networks should be separated from fixed networks(horizontal separation)5.1.1 Vertical separation of networksThe issues around vertical separation of local access to o<strong>the</strong>r parts of <strong>the</strong>network are relatively straightforward. The case for vertical separationessentially rests on reduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> opportunities for anti-competitive behaviour<strong>and</strong> so reduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> complexity of regulation. If a firm with essential facilities isvertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated (like Telkom), <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>y have tremendous scope forbehav<strong>in</strong>g anti-competitively. This could occur by ei<strong>the</strong>r grant<strong>in</strong>g lessfavourable access to competitors than to <strong>the</strong>ir own downstream service(different price, quality or customer access dial<strong>in</strong>g 5 ) or overpric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>monopoly component (local access) <strong>and</strong> cross-subsidis<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> long-distancenetwork to <strong>the</strong> detriment of competitors. If <strong>the</strong>re is vertical separation, <strong>the</strong>n<strong>the</strong>re is little <strong>in</strong>centive for discrim<strong>in</strong>atory access provision or crosssubsidisation,which leaves <strong>the</strong> regulator to concentrate on ensur<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong>reis no monopoly pric<strong>in</strong>g of access only. The cost sav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this case is aregulatory one.The economic argument aga<strong>in</strong>st vertical separation is that it will destroy anyeconomies of scope that may exist between <strong>the</strong> two networks. If <strong>the</strong>se aresignificant, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> potential efficiency cost may well outweigh <strong>the</strong> regulatorycost of closer supervision of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent. An equally powerful argumentaga<strong>in</strong>st vertical separation is <strong>the</strong> cost of undertak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> exercise when <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent is already <strong>in</strong>tegrated. The cost is not only <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternal restructur<strong>in</strong>gcost but also <strong>the</strong> time delays <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> deregulation process.There is no clear side on which <strong>the</strong> decision of vertical separation should fall.In <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> UK, <strong>the</strong> desire to have a rapid privatisation <strong>in</strong>telecommunications led <strong>the</strong>m to reject <strong>the</strong> vertical separation model 6(Armstrong et al 1995:215). In contrast, <strong>the</strong> USA adopted <strong>the</strong> verticalseparation model when <strong>the</strong>y brought an antitrust case aga<strong>in</strong>st AT&T <strong>in</strong>1974alleg<strong>in</strong>g anti-competitive behaviour aga<strong>in</strong>st o<strong>the</strong>r long distance networks. Thecase was f<strong>in</strong>ally settled 8 years later <strong>and</strong> resulted <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> separation of localaccess <strong>in</strong> 1984. More recently <strong>the</strong>re have been attempts by some of <strong>the</strong>RBOCs (Regional Bell Operat<strong>in</strong>g Companies) to get permission to move <strong>in</strong>tolong distance, which have been resisted by <strong>the</strong> regulator with <strong>the</strong> conditionthat greater local access competition must proceed it.Consider<strong>in</strong>g that South Africa has already gone some way down <strong>the</strong>deregulation path without break<strong>in</strong>g up Telkom, suggests that it would bedifficult to do it at this po<strong>in</strong>t. It would also be difficult to get equity partnerconsent for <strong>the</strong> process, with <strong>the</strong> likely result that <strong>the</strong>y will pursue <strong>the</strong> matter <strong>in</strong>court caus<strong>in</strong>g fur<strong>the</strong>r delays to <strong>the</strong> deregulation process. This reason<strong>in</strong>g islikely to rule <strong>the</strong> day, mak<strong>in</strong>g it largely unnecessary to really evaluate <strong>the</strong>costs <strong>and</strong> benefits of each policy <strong>in</strong> South Africa. The fact that this is not on5 Forc<strong>in</strong>g customers to dial an access code to use <strong>the</strong> compet<strong>in</strong>g long distance networks, <strong>the</strong>rebyrais<strong>in</strong>g switch<strong>in</strong>g costs.6 Armstrong et al (1995) note that ano<strong>the</strong>r reason for avoid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> breakup was that BT managementwas opposed to <strong>the</strong> idea <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> regulator needed <strong>the</strong>ir support for a rapid privatisation.51


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong><strong>the</strong> table for discussion at <strong>the</strong> moment <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> models considered arejust <strong>the</strong> number of full facilities based competitors, supports this reason<strong>in</strong>g.If <strong>the</strong>re is to be vertical <strong>in</strong>tegration, <strong>the</strong>n naturally <strong>the</strong>re needs to be at leastseparate account<strong>in</strong>g to facilitate regulation of local access <strong>and</strong> competitionanalysis. However, given Telkom’s history of conduct s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> partialprivatisation 7 , <strong>the</strong>re may be good reason to ensure that <strong>the</strong>re is closecompetitive oversight of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terconnection process <strong>and</strong> agreements.5.1.2 Vertical separation of services from networksEven if <strong>the</strong>re is no separation of networks, <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong> possibility of separat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> service component from <strong>the</strong> network component. The reason<strong>in</strong>g for thisroute is <strong>the</strong> same as for separat<strong>in</strong>g networks – to remove <strong>the</strong> possibility ofanti-competitive practice by <strong>the</strong> owner of <strong>the</strong> essential facility. The argumentsaga<strong>in</strong>st are also <strong>the</strong> same – economies of scope <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> cost of <strong>in</strong>dustryrestructur<strong>in</strong>g. The range of services that could be separated <strong>in</strong>clude localbasic voice, long distance basic voice, VANS <strong>and</strong> broadcast<strong>in</strong>g.In <strong>the</strong> case of basic voice, local or long distance, <strong>the</strong>re appears to be a strongeconomies of scope case aga<strong>in</strong>st vertical separation. In <strong>the</strong> USA, where <strong>the</strong>path to deregulation was vertical separation of markets, <strong>the</strong> RBOCs <strong>and</strong>AT&T were still permitted to offer basic voice. There are equally compell<strong>in</strong>greasons for not separat<strong>in</strong>g VANS <strong>and</strong> broadcast<strong>in</strong>g from network provision.However, <strong>the</strong>re is precedent for do<strong>in</strong>g so from <strong>the</strong> UK where <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbentwas prevented from enter<strong>in</strong>g broadcast<strong>in</strong>g services on <strong>the</strong> basis of assist<strong>in</strong>gentry of cable television companies <strong>in</strong>to local access telephony. The USApursued <strong>the</strong> same route <strong>and</strong> also prevented <strong>the</strong> RBOCs from enter<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>VANS sector <strong>in</strong>itially.In <strong>the</strong> South Africa case, momentum may aga<strong>in</strong> decide <strong>the</strong> direction of policy.The exist<strong>in</strong>g regulatory regime does not restrict Telkom from enter<strong>in</strong>gdownstream markets. However, it has not been that successful <strong>in</strong> do<strong>in</strong>g so todate, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that vertical separation may not be that necessary. However,Telkom has had little <strong>in</strong>centive to make a success of downstream services, asall service providers must lease <strong>the</strong>ir l<strong>in</strong>es from it anyway. However, once<strong>the</strong>re is facilities competition, <strong>the</strong>re may be greater <strong>in</strong>centive for Telkom to notonly enter <strong>the</strong>se markets but also behave anti-competitively.Despite <strong>the</strong> momentum <strong>in</strong> regulation, it may be feasible to separateVANS/broadcast<strong>in</strong>g services at this po<strong>in</strong>t precisely because Telkom has notmade large <strong>in</strong>roads <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> market.5.1.3 Horizontal separation of mobile servicesHorizontal separation of mobile services would require that no firm hasoperates or has hold<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> both fixed local access <strong>and</strong> mobile. The case forseparation is twofold: a) as fixed local access is an essential facility, <strong>the</strong>provider can discrim<strong>in</strong>ate aga<strong>in</strong>st its mobile rivals, <strong>and</strong> b) that mobile is one of<strong>the</strong> few close competitors to fixed local access <strong>and</strong> so it may be desirable to7 In particular <strong>the</strong>ir deal<strong>in</strong>gs with VANS operators, deny<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m additional capacity after alleg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ywere provid<strong>in</strong>g clients with telephony <strong>and</strong> not just data services.52


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>separate <strong>the</strong> markets to ensure maximum competition. The case aga<strong>in</strong>st is<strong>the</strong> economies of scope argument.The second argument for horizontal separation is a potentially very powerfulargument <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> South African scenario. As discussed <strong>in</strong> section 4, <strong>the</strong>re isunlikely to be a cable competitor on a broad scale <strong>in</strong> South Africa due to lowaverage <strong>in</strong>comes <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> current technology choice of satellite for Pay TV. Itis also unlikely that a significant residential local access competitor willemerge unless <strong>the</strong>re is some form of exclusivity granted (<strong>and</strong> even <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>reis doubt). The most likely discipl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g force from <strong>in</strong>dustry players will comefrom mobile <strong>and</strong> so it would be advisable to avoid corrupt<strong>in</strong>g this competitionby allow<strong>in</strong>g cross-ownership. It is also relatively easy to implement as <strong>the</strong>current cross-hold<strong>in</strong>g is exactly that – a share hold<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> not an <strong>in</strong>tegratedorganisation. Restructur<strong>in</strong>g would come at little cost.5.2 EntryThe key entry issues <strong>in</strong> telecommunications deregulation are:• Whe<strong>the</strong>r or not to restrict entry <strong>in</strong>to any parts of <strong>the</strong> market• How to deal with possible entry deterrence if entry is permitted• Whe<strong>the</strong>r or not to actively assist <strong>the</strong> entrant(s) <strong>in</strong> compet<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent• How to deal with asymmetric regulation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent <strong>and</strong> entrant(s)5.2.1 To Restrict Entry or NotA primary question <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> South African regulatory debate at present iswhe<strong>the</strong>r to open up <strong>the</strong> telecommunications sector completely or merely<strong>in</strong>troduce one or two new entrants.The Duopoly AppraochThe option favoured by Telkom <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> primary contender – a Transtel/Esitelledconsortium – is for a duopoly with exclusivity for ano<strong>the</strong>r 3-5 years.Telkom also would want a so-called ‘level play<strong>in</strong>g field’ where <strong>the</strong> entrantwould have all <strong>the</strong> same universal service obligations as Telkom. There isalso considerable government support for this approach. It appears as if muchof <strong>the</strong> government support comes from <strong>the</strong> fact that a fur<strong>the</strong>r exclusivity periodwith a duopoly will maximise <strong>the</strong> revenue objective of government. The IPO ofTelkom <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> sale of Transtel/Esitel will both realise higher prices if anexclusive duopoly is <strong>in</strong> place – a premium to reflect <strong>the</strong> abnormal profits <strong>the</strong>yare likely to get <strong>in</strong> future.The public rationale for support<strong>in</strong>g such a policy is a l<strong>in</strong>e of reason<strong>in</strong>g thatgoes like this - no firm is go<strong>in</strong>g to enter local access <strong>in</strong> residential <strong>and</strong>underserviced areas unless <strong>the</strong>y are forced to do so <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir licenceagreements. If this is <strong>the</strong> case, no firm will bid for <strong>the</strong> licence unless itreceived some protection from o<strong>the</strong>r entrants <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> more lucrative parts of <strong>the</strong>market – namely long distance <strong>and</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess local access (<strong>in</strong> essencema<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> cross-subsidy).53


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Clearly this approach has a stifl<strong>in</strong>g effect on competition – that is why <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent, ma<strong>in</strong> contender <strong>and</strong> revenue-maximis<strong>in</strong>g government support <strong>the</strong>approach, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry does not. The approach has some meritif it is able to permanently alter <strong>the</strong> market structure of local access <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>short exclusivity period allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> regulator to ‘exit’ control of <strong>in</strong>cumbentpric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> medium term. Evidence from o<strong>the</strong>r countries suggests that thisis unlikely to be <strong>the</strong> case. The UK pursued this model <strong>and</strong> after a seven yearduopoly period <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent still had 97% of <strong>the</strong> residential local accessmarket, 87% of <strong>the</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess local access market <strong>and</strong> 76% of <strong>the</strong> Internetmarket. Clearly this policy had no significant long-run impact on <strong>the</strong> marketstructure <strong>and</strong> no reduction <strong>in</strong> regulatory activity <strong>and</strong> hence regulatory cost.The approach may also has merit if it is able to significantly raise access totelephony by residents of underserviced areas (social goal). This is also aquestionable assumption. The primary tool for universal service will be <strong>the</strong>non-distortionary USF, which raises money from a tax on alltelecommunications operators. The duopoly approach is an attempt tosupplement this with <strong>in</strong>ternal cross-subsidy – an <strong>in</strong>efficient alternative that willhave bus<strong>in</strong>ess local access <strong>and</strong> long-distance support<strong>in</strong>g residential access.Rais<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> penetration of telephony is probably better served through rais<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> USF tax ra<strong>the</strong>r than distort<strong>in</strong>g competition, especially if <strong>the</strong> adjustment hasto come eventually.Open <strong>Competition</strong> ApproachEvidence from most countries suggests that <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> residential local accessmarket <strong>the</strong>re is a considerable natural monopoly element result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g highly dom<strong>in</strong>ant even with completely open entry. Ifduopoly is not go<strong>in</strong>g to succeed <strong>in</strong> chang<strong>in</strong>g this ei<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>n tight regulation oflocal access will rema<strong>in</strong> a part of regulatory life for <strong>the</strong> foreseeable futureregardless of entry strategy. If this is <strong>the</strong> case, it seems that one should reap<strong>the</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s from competition <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r parts of <strong>the</strong> telecommunications marketnow ra<strong>the</strong>r than later, while support<strong>in</strong>g some long-term market structurechange <strong>in</strong> local access.This approach would open up <strong>the</strong> market for long-distance network <strong>and</strong> resaleto make this a competitive component. This is a potentially competitive market<strong>and</strong> so is likely to see entry. It also offers significant ga<strong>in</strong>s for bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong><strong>the</strong> Internet, both of which make considerable use of <strong>the</strong> long-distancenetwork. In this way <strong>the</strong> policy supports <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>termediate role of <strong>the</strong> sector <strong>in</strong>grow<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> South Africa.In <strong>the</strong> local access market <strong>the</strong>re are two possible approaches. One approachwould be to open entry completely. In this scenario, entry is likely to occur <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess component, l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>esses to <strong>the</strong> long-distance networks (as<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> USA). If <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent is cross-subsidis<strong>in</strong>g residential <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> amountof bypass will be greater. To ensure that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent is not overly exposedto bypass, <strong>the</strong> universal service approach should be entirely through <strong>the</strong> USF<strong>and</strong> not built <strong>in</strong>to contracts. Entry could also be encouraged <strong>in</strong>to residentiallocal access through bidd<strong>in</strong>g for USF funds to <strong>in</strong>stall local loops <strong>in</strong>underserviced areas (a successful USA approach).54


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>The alternative is to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> a cross-subsidy approach <strong>and</strong> allow entry <strong>in</strong>to<strong>the</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess local access on condition of certa<strong>in</strong> residential obligations. Thisappears less attractive as it requires considerable regulatory oversight <strong>and</strong> isdistortionary <strong>and</strong> so less preferable to a rais<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> USF contribution.Under <strong>the</strong> more open competition approach, <strong>the</strong> likely ma<strong>in</strong> competitor forlocal access will be mobile. This be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> case, <strong>the</strong> regulator would need toensure that no cross-hold<strong>in</strong>gs exist to limit scope for strategic behaviour by<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent.With both <strong>the</strong> duopoly <strong>and</strong> open competition model, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent will haveconsiderable market power <strong>and</strong> scope to limit entry. The regulator will need tohave tight control of prices by <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent (but not <strong>the</strong> entrant), <strong>and</strong> adoptmeasures to limit entry deterrance <strong>and</strong> promote entry. These are discussedbelow.5.2.2 Deal<strong>in</strong>g with Entry DeterrenceAs noted <strong>in</strong> section 4, <strong>the</strong> primary means for entry deterrence is throughunfavourable <strong>in</strong>terconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> PSTN <strong>and</strong> customer switch<strong>in</strong>gcosts. The regulator has a difficult task <strong>in</strong> ensur<strong>in</strong>g fair <strong>in</strong>terconnection quality<strong>and</strong> access pric<strong>in</strong>g. Interconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g is dealt with <strong>in</strong> detail <strong>in</strong> 5.3.The switch<strong>in</strong>g cost issue is more clear. For long-distance network competition,pre-selection of default provider should be available <strong>and</strong> short access codesfor long-distance service providers. Number portability for local access is afur<strong>the</strong>r support policy. If competition <strong>in</strong> local access is not expected to besignificant anyway, it may be prudent to delay <strong>the</strong> implementation of fullnumber portability <strong>in</strong> local access as it has cost implications for <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent<strong>and</strong> any entrant.5.2.3 To Actively Assist Entry or NotEven a so-called level play<strong>in</strong>g field will not always result <strong>in</strong> significant entry<strong>and</strong> competition because <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent is start<strong>in</strong>g from a position of 100%market share <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>y still own a strategic resource – <strong>in</strong>formation. Informationabout who <strong>the</strong> customers are <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir behaviour. They also have a largeamount of technological learn<strong>in</strong>g beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong>m. As a result, <strong>the</strong> entrants willrema<strong>in</strong> at a disadvantage. If <strong>the</strong> regulator is <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> chang<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> marketstructure of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry to lower regulatory costs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> long-run, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>ycan try favour entrants to ensure more rapid entry. There are a number ofways of do<strong>in</strong>g this:• Reduc<strong>in</strong>g sunk costs – allow entrants <strong>in</strong> local access or long-distance tomake use of poles <strong>and</strong> ducts of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent to roll out <strong>in</strong>frastructure• Reduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terconnection prices – allow<strong>in</strong>g below-cost <strong>in</strong>terconnection toallow entrants to overcome <strong>in</strong>itial learn<strong>in</strong>g costs• Favourable access to USF subsidies – <strong>the</strong> auction<strong>in</strong>g of subsidies toprovide local access would favour new entrant bidders• Reduce universal service obligations – allow entrants to make a lowerpayment to <strong>the</strong> USF or <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> duopoly model, to have lower contractualdem<strong>and</strong>s.55


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>All <strong>the</strong>se policies may be desirable <strong>in</strong> South Africa. The last option may bepolitically sensitive to implement if an open competition model is taken,because <strong>the</strong> rationale is to ra<strong>the</strong>r raise <strong>the</strong> contribution to <strong>the</strong> USF to supportuniversal service ra<strong>the</strong>r than use distortionary cross-subsidisation.5.2.4 Asymmetric regulationIn a more liberal telecommunications environment, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent will rema<strong>in</strong>regulated <strong>in</strong> all markets where it is dom<strong>in</strong>ant, but entrants will not. Thisasymmetric regulation may distort entry conditions.If <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent has a price cap basket that <strong>in</strong>cludes both local access <strong>and</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r prices, <strong>the</strong>n it would be possible to reduce prices on long-distancedramatically to fight off competition <strong>and</strong> raise residential local access chargeswhile still rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> price cap bounds. This will be detrimental touniversal service <strong>and</strong> limit entry to <strong>the</strong> more competitive components of <strong>the</strong>market. To elim<strong>in</strong>ate this possibility, it would be preferable to have a separateprice cap for local access.Forc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent to drive down <strong>the</strong> price of a particular service through aprice cap, may also reduce prices below those that would attract entrants <strong>in</strong>to<strong>the</strong> market. This may arise because <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent can price at marg<strong>in</strong>al costas its fixed costs are already sunk, but entrants need to price at long-runmarg<strong>in</strong>al cost which <strong>in</strong>cludes <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>stallation of capacity.F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>the</strong>re is a danger to forc<strong>in</strong>g cross-subsidisation of services by <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent. In <strong>the</strong> face of cream-skimm<strong>in</strong>g, this regulation could make <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent unprofitable. The implication is that <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> open competition model,<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent must be allowed to price local access accord<strong>in</strong>g to costs. TheUSF would <strong>the</strong>n play a more important role <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g access charges forpoor households <strong>in</strong>stead of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternal cross-subsidy of Telkom.5.3 Pric<strong>in</strong>gLong after <strong>the</strong> market is opened to competition, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent will havesufficient market power to warrant strict price regulation. The entrants willusually not warrant such regulation as <strong>the</strong>y lack <strong>the</strong> market power. Thissection looks at how f<strong>in</strong>al consumer prices <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terconnection prices shouldbe regulated.5.3.1 F<strong>in</strong>al consumer pricesThe policy of choice by ICASA for f<strong>in</strong>al consumer price regulation is <strong>the</strong> pricecap. The price cap has <strong>the</strong> potentially desirable feature of <strong>in</strong>centivis<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>cumbent to reduce costs. However, it also has its problems. Primaryamongst <strong>the</strong>m is that because costs are uncerta<strong>in</strong> it can lead to politicallyembarrass<strong>in</strong>g w<strong>in</strong>dfall ga<strong>in</strong>s for <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent or severe losses. The fear ofimpos<strong>in</strong>g losses on <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> subsequent review process,means that regulators tend to err on <strong>the</strong> side of caution <strong>and</strong> offer generousprice cap targets. South Africa is a case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t with a mere 1.5% below<strong>in</strong>flation target for <strong>the</strong> first years of <strong>the</strong> exclusivity period <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> face ofdecl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g costs from technological change.56


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>One of <strong>the</strong> price cap issues is what to <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundle. As alreadymentioned, it is advisable to remove monopoly components <strong>in</strong>to a separateprice cap to avoid transfer pric<strong>in</strong>g by an <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>cumbent. This wouldleave one price cap for local access <strong>and</strong> one for all o<strong>the</strong>r prices. Somecountries have <strong>the</strong>n left certa<strong>in</strong> prices outside of <strong>the</strong> cap under <strong>the</strong> reason<strong>in</strong>gthat those markets were competitive. However, <strong>the</strong> trend now is to <strong>in</strong>clude allo<strong>the</strong>r prices as <strong>the</strong> scope for strategic anti-competitive behaviour by <strong>the</strong>dom<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>in</strong>cumbent is enormous (<strong>the</strong> USA is a case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t withprogressively greater price control of AT&T).There may also be consideration of an earn<strong>in</strong>gs shar<strong>in</strong>g approach (discussed<strong>in</strong> section 2). Under this scheme, any under or overshoot<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> target isshared between <strong>in</strong>cumbent <strong>and</strong> consumer. The <strong>in</strong>centives are less highpowered but <strong>the</strong>y are politically more manageable.Ano<strong>the</strong>r pric<strong>in</strong>g issue is <strong>the</strong> structure of prices. Local prices are ord<strong>in</strong>arilymade up of a monthly access charge <strong>in</strong> order to cover <strong>the</strong> fixed costs ofestablish<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> network <strong>and</strong> a usage charge to cover marg<strong>in</strong>al costs (whichare very low <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of telecommunications). Optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g suggestsrais<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> access charge well above marg<strong>in</strong>al cost as dem<strong>and</strong> is <strong>in</strong>elastic<strong>and</strong> lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> usage charge closer to marg<strong>in</strong>al cost as dem<strong>and</strong> is elastic(Ramsey pric<strong>in</strong>g). Universal service suggests <strong>the</strong> opposite, with low accesscharges to allow low-<strong>in</strong>come households to get access. As each user needsto cover <strong>the</strong> costs of l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m to <strong>the</strong> network, an alternative is to have amenu of tariffs to suit <strong>the</strong> preferences of each consumer (this is not unfairprice discrim<strong>in</strong>ation as <strong>the</strong> consumers have a choice from a bundle ofoptions). The high-usage customer (bus<strong>in</strong>ess or heavy Internet user) wouldopt for a high access charge, low usage charge option while <strong>the</strong> poorerhousehold would opt for a low access charge, high usage charge option.An optimal range of pric<strong>in</strong>g options is unlikely to emerge <strong>in</strong> a monopolyscenario, but will emerge under competition (note that <strong>in</strong> cellular <strong>in</strong> SA <strong>the</strong>reare many such pric<strong>in</strong>g options from pay-as-you-go – with high usage rates –to subscription options, while <strong>in</strong> fixed l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong>re are less options). Thissuggests that while <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent rema<strong>in</strong>s dom<strong>in</strong>ant, <strong>the</strong> regulator may wishto impose pric<strong>in</strong>g structures as well as price caps to get optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>market. The precendent for such action is <strong>the</strong> UK where early <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong>privatised model options for low-usage customers was enforced 8 (result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>1.5million users tak<strong>in</strong>g this option) <strong>and</strong> more recently a high usage optionenforced (for heavy Internet users).5.3.2 Interconnection (Access) pric<strong>in</strong>gThe approach chosen <strong>in</strong> South Africa for <strong>in</strong>terconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g is one ofpric<strong>in</strong>g at LRIC (long-run <strong>in</strong>cremental cost). However, because so many costsare common, it is very difficult to come to any firm decision on what can be<strong>in</strong>cluded or not – provid<strong>in</strong>g scope for abuse. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>se agreements mustbe negotiated <strong>and</strong> if unresolved <strong>the</strong> regulator will <strong>in</strong>tervene. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that<strong>the</strong>re will rema<strong>in</strong> a monopoly on part of <strong>the</strong> network, strategic behaviour willresult <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g outcomes:8 Armstrong et al (1995)57


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>a) if two networks do not compete <strong>in</strong> any markets (as is <strong>the</strong> case of twonational providers from different countries) <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> outcome mayresemble costs more closely,b) If <strong>the</strong>re is uneven traffic flow, one provider will deliberately overprice <strong>in</strong>order to ga<strong>in</strong> an effective subsidy from users of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r network (acommon practice amongst African national providers <strong>and</strong> one whichTelkom could employ <strong>in</strong> a duopoly scenario)c) If <strong>the</strong> two networks do compete <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r segments of <strong>the</strong> market (such asprovision of long distance communications) <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>in</strong>centive todeliberately overprice <strong>in</strong> order to ru<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitiveness of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rnetwork <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r market.As Telkom will have a dom<strong>in</strong>ant position <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> local access market regardlessof model chosen, it is likely that <strong>the</strong>y will have <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive to overpriceaccess.An alternative is to bundle <strong>in</strong>terconnection pric<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> price cap bundle –a global price cap as suggested by Laffont & Tirole (2000). This has <strong>the</strong>advantage of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent view<strong>in</strong>g access as just ano<strong>the</strong>r product. If itoverprices local access <strong>the</strong>n it needs to lower o<strong>the</strong>r prices to compensate.This may mean that long distance prices are not overly high <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> end.The level of price for <strong>in</strong>terconnection needs to recover a portion of <strong>the</strong> ‘accessdeficit’ from o<strong>the</strong>r firms if <strong>the</strong>re is no scope for cross-subsidy (i.e. <strong>the</strong> openmarket option). In this case, <strong>the</strong> regulator needs to ensure that <strong>the</strong>re is nocost transfer from <strong>the</strong> long-distance operations of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>cumbent.5.4 QualityThe existence of price controls often necessitates <strong>the</strong> use of quality controlstoo. The reason is that a price-regulated firm has <strong>in</strong>centives to lower <strong>the</strong>quality of service to meet price controls <strong>in</strong>stead of lower<strong>in</strong>g costs. The currentcontract with Telkom for <strong>the</strong> exclusivity period has such measures. As Telkomis likely to still have some price controls <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> post-exclusivity period due to<strong>the</strong>ir dom<strong>in</strong>ance, quality measures would be appropriate too. There are arange of quality measures that can be used, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g:• call completion rate• faults per 100 l<strong>in</strong>es• speed for repair<strong>in</strong>g faults• speed of <strong>in</strong>stall<strong>in</strong>g a l<strong>in</strong>e• public phone box ma<strong>in</strong>tenance <strong>and</strong> repairQuality can be <strong>in</strong>corporated through f<strong>in</strong>ancial penalties (current method),<strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g a quality <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> price cap, or an <strong>in</strong>formal warn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong>discipl<strong>in</strong>e through more str<strong>in</strong>gent price caps <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> next round.58


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Conclud<strong>in</strong>g RemarksThere are many <strong>in</strong>dustry analysts who view <strong>the</strong> past 5 year exclusivity periodof Telkom to be a mistake by cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g to hamper downstream bus<strong>in</strong>esses.These analysts will argue for complete liberalisation. O<strong>the</strong>r groups of societywill view <strong>the</strong> universal service rollout <strong>and</strong> low loss of jobs as success po<strong>in</strong>tsfor <strong>the</strong> policy, <strong>and</strong> will look to cont<strong>in</strong>ue this <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> form of an exclusiveduopoly. The WTO commitment ensures that we need to at least move to alimited entry policy. However, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> end, <strong>the</strong> policy framework forderegulation of <strong>the</strong> telecommunications <strong>in</strong>dustry is go<strong>in</strong>g to be a politicalprocess.Ayogu <strong>and</strong> Hodge (2000) note that <strong>the</strong> distribution of ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>and</strong> losses <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>full competition model favour <strong>the</strong> wealthy <strong>in</strong> society – <strong>the</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>heavy users of telecommunications. The low-<strong>in</strong>come groups are likely to bearall <strong>the</strong> short-term adjustment costs (job losses) for some uncerta<strong>in</strong> futurereward (jobs from downstream users of telecommunications <strong>and</strong> lower priceson future telephone use). Given <strong>the</strong> constituency of <strong>the</strong> government, thissuggests a gradual liberalisation approach may be preferred, where revenuemaximisation occurs <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s can be transferred to <strong>the</strong> losers throughfiscal policy.If <strong>the</strong> full competition model is to be adopted, it needs to be structured toprovide stronger universal service support <strong>and</strong> deliver downstream benefits tolow-<strong>in</strong>come groups rapidly. This suggests maybe rais<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> USF levy <strong>and</strong>pursu<strong>in</strong>g strict competition <strong>and</strong> regulatory enforcement <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector to lowerprices <strong>and</strong> benefit downstream job creators.59


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>BibliographyArmstrong M, Cowan S. Vickers J. 1995. Regulatory Reform: EconomicAnalysis <strong>and</strong> British Experience. MIT Press, LondonAyogu M, Hodge J. 2000. ‘The socio-economic context <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutionalfoundations of privatisation <strong>and</strong> regulatory reform <strong>in</strong> South Africa’, GDNConference, December 10-13, Tokyo, 2000Bergman L, Doyle C, Gual J, Hultkrantz L, Neven D, Roller L, Waverman L.1998. Europe’s Network Industries: Conflict<strong>in</strong>g Priorities. CEPR, UK.Cave, M “Alternative <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Infrastructures: Their <strong>Competition</strong>Policy <strong>and</strong> Market Structure Implications”, 1995Hodge J. 2000. ‘Liberalis<strong>in</strong>g Communications Services <strong>in</strong> South Africa’,Development Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Africa, vol. 17 (3), Sept.ICASA. 2000. “Notice <strong>in</strong> respect of a review of fees <strong>and</strong> charges <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> publicswitched telecommunications sector” Government Gazette Number:21925 General Notice Number: 4715ITU, “Trends <strong>in</strong> Telecommunication Reform 1999: Convergence <strong>and</strong><strong>Regulation</strong>”, 1999Kridel D, Sapp<strong>in</strong>gton D, Weisman D. 1996. ‘The Effects of Incentive<strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong> <strong>Industry</strong>: A Survey’. Journal ofregulatory Economics, vol 9, pp. 269-306Laffont J, Tirole J. 2000. <strong>Competition</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>. MIT Press,Cambridge, MA.MediaAfrica.com. 2000. South African Internet Market 2000.M-Web. 2000. Annual ReportPosner R. 1971. “Taxation by <strong>Regulation</strong>”, Bell Journal of Economics <strong>and</strong>Management Science. Vol. 2(1). Pp. 22-50Purton, P. 2000. “Former Monopoly loses significant market share”, F<strong>in</strong>ancialTimes SurveyResende M. 2000. “Regulatory Regimes <strong>and</strong> Efficiency <strong>in</strong> US LocalTelephony”. Oxford Economic Papers. Vol 52 pp. 447-470RSA. 1995. White Paper on <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Policy.RSA. 1996. <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Act 103SATRA. 1999. Interconnection Guidel<strong>in</strong>es.SATRA. 1999. <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Number<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> Twenty-first Century.Consultative Document July.Statistics South Africa. 1995. Income <strong>and</strong> Expenditure SurveyStigler, G. 1971. “The Theory of economic <strong>Regulation</strong>”. Bell Journal ofEconomics <strong>and</strong> Management Science. Vol. 2(1). pp. 3-21Telkom Annual Reports 1995-200060


<strong>Competition</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong>Telkom. 2001. “Accomplishments <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Telecommunications</strong> Sector dur<strong>in</strong>gSouth Africa’s Democratisation Process”, http:www.telkom.co.za/government_ regulatory/<strong>in</strong>dex.shtmlWEFA. 1997. Social Account<strong>in</strong>g Matrix61

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!