12.07.2015 Views

Managing Credit Risk in Corporate Bond Portfolios : A Practitioner's ...

Managing Credit Risk in Corporate Bond Portfolios : A Practitioner's ...

Managing Credit Risk in Corporate Bond Portfolios : A Practitioner's ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> <strong>Portfolios</strong>A Practitioner’s GuideSRICHANDER RAMASWAMYJohn Wiley & Sons, Inc.


<strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> <strong>Portfolios</strong>A Practitioner’s Guide


THE FRANK J. FABOZZI SERIESFixed Income Securities, Second Edition by Frank J. FabozziFocus on Value: A <strong>Corporate</strong> and Investor Guide to Wealth Creation byJames L. Grant and James A. AbateHandbook of Global Fixed Income Calculations by Dragomir Krg<strong>in</strong><strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> a <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Portfolio by Leland E. Crabbe and Frank J.FabozziReal Options and Option-Embedded Securities by William T. MooreCapital Budget<strong>in</strong>g: Theory and Practice by Pamela P. Peterson and Frank J.FabozziThe Exchange-Traded Funds Manual by Gary L. Gast<strong>in</strong>eauProfessional Perspectives on Fixed Income Portfolio Management, Volume3 edited by Frank J. FabozziInvest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Emerg<strong>in</strong>g Fixed Income Markets edited by Frank J. Fabozziand Efstathia Pilar<strong>in</strong>uHandbook of Alternative Assets by Mark J. P. AnsonThe Exchange-Traded Funds Manual by Gary L. Gast<strong>in</strong>eauThe Global Money Markets by Frank J. Fabozzi, Steven V. Mann, andMoorad ChoudhryThe Handbook of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Instruments edited by Frank J. FabozziCollateralized Debt Obligations: Structures and Analysis by Laurie S.Goodman and Frank J. FabozziInterest Rate, Term Structure, and Valuation Model<strong>in</strong>g edited by Frank J.FabozziInvestment Performance Measurement by Bruce J. FeibelThe Handbook of Equity Style Management edited by T. Daniel Cogg<strong>in</strong>and Frank J. FabozziThe Theory and Practice of Investment Management edited by Frank J.Fabozzi and Harry M. MarkowitzFoundations of Economic Value Added: Second Edition by James L. GrantF<strong>in</strong>ancial Management and Analysis: Second Edition by Frank J. Fabozziand Pamela P. Peterson<strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> <strong>Portfolios</strong>: A Practitioner’s Guideby Srichander RamaswamyProfessional Perspectives <strong>in</strong> Fixed Income Portfolio Management, VolumeFour by Frank J. Fabozzi


<strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> <strong>Portfolios</strong>A Practitioner’s GuideSRICHANDER RAMASWAMYJohn Wiley & Sons, Inc.


Copyright © 2004 by Srichander Ramaswamy. All rights reserved.Published by John Wiley & Sons, Inc., Hoboken, New JerseyPublished simultaneously <strong>in</strong> CanadaNo part of this publication may be reproduced, stored <strong>in</strong> a retrieval system, or transmitted <strong>in</strong>any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopy<strong>in</strong>g, record<strong>in</strong>g, scann<strong>in</strong>g, or otherwise,except as permitted under Section 107 or 108 of the 1976 United States CopyrightAct, without either the prior written permission of the Publisher, or authorization throughpayment of the appropriate per-copy fee to the Copyright Clearance Center, Inc., 222 RosewoodDrive, Danvers, MA 01923, 978-750-8400, fax 978-750-4470, or on the web atwww.copyright.com. Requests to the Publisher for permission should be addressed to thePermissions Department, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 111 River Street, Hoboken, NJ 07030,201-748-6011, fax 201-748-6008, e-mail: permcoord<strong>in</strong>ator@wiley.com.Limit of Liability/Disclaimer of Warranty: While the publisher and author have used their bestefforts <strong>in</strong> prepar<strong>in</strong>g this book, they make no representations or warranties with respect to theaccuracy or completeness of the contents of this book and specifically disclaim any impliedwarranties of merchantability or fitness for a particular purpose. No warranty may be createdor extended by sales representatives or written sales materials. The advice and strategies conta<strong>in</strong>edhere<strong>in</strong> may not be suitable for your situation. You should consult with a professionalwhere appropriate. Neither the publisher nor author shall be liable for any loss of profit or anyother commercial damages, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g but not limited to special, <strong>in</strong>cidental, consequential, orother damages.For general <strong>in</strong>formation on our other products and services, or technical support, please contactour Customer Care Department with<strong>in</strong> the United States at 800-762-2974, outside theUnited States at 317-572-3993 or fax 317-572-4002.Wiley also publishes its books <strong>in</strong> a variety of electronic formats. Some content that appears <strong>in</strong>pr<strong>in</strong>t may not be available <strong>in</strong> electronic books.For more <strong>in</strong>formation about Wiley products, visit our web site at www.wiley.com.ISBN: 0-471-43037-4Pr<strong>in</strong>ted <strong>in</strong> the United States of America10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1


ContentsFOREWORDPREFACEXIXIIICHAPTER 1 1IntroductionMotivation 1Summary of the Book 2CHAPTER 2Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 5Probability Theory 5Characteriz<strong>in</strong>g Probability Distributions 5Useful Probability Distributions 8Jo<strong>in</strong>t Distributions 10Stochastic Processes 12L<strong>in</strong>ear Algebra 13Properties of Vectors 14Transpose of a Matrix 14Inverse of a Matrix 14Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors 15Diagonalization of a Matrix 15Properties of Symmetric Matrices 15Cholesky Decomposition 16Markov Matrix 17Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal Component Analysis 19Questions 21CHAPTER 3The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 23Features of <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong>s 23<strong>Bond</strong> Collateralization 24Investment <strong>Risk</strong>s 26<strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Trad<strong>in</strong>g 28Trad<strong>in</strong>g Costs 28v


viCONTENTSPortfolio Management Style 30Pric<strong>in</strong>g Anomalies 31Role of <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong>s 32Relative Market Size 35Historical Performance 37The Case for <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong>s 40Central Bank Reserves 40Pension Funds 47Questions 50CHAPTER 4Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong> 51Interest Rate <strong>Risk</strong> 51Modified Duration 52Convexity 53Approximat<strong>in</strong>g Price Changes 53<strong>Bond</strong>s with Embedded Options 54Portfolio Aggregates 56Dynamics of the Yield Curve 57Other Sources of Market <strong>Risk</strong> 61Market <strong>Risk</strong> Model 61Questions 65CHAPTER 5Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 67Elements of <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 67Probability of Default 68Recovery Rate 75Rat<strong>in</strong>g Migrations 77Quantify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 81Expected Loss Under Default Mode 83Unexpected Loss Under Default Mode 86Expected Loss Under Migration Mode 88Unexpected Loss Under Migration Mode 91Numerical Example 92Questions 94CHAPTER 6Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 95Quantify<strong>in</strong>g Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 95


ContentsviiDefault Correlation 98Relationship to Loss Correlation 99Estimat<strong>in</strong>g Default Correlation 100Default Mode: Two-<strong>Bond</strong> Portfolio 102Estimat<strong>in</strong>g Asset Return Correlation 104Factor Models 106Approximate Asset Return Correlations 109<strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Under Migration Mode 111Comput<strong>in</strong>g Jo<strong>in</strong>t Migration Probabilities 114Comput<strong>in</strong>g Jo<strong>in</strong>t <strong>Credit</strong> Loss 114Migration Mode: Two-<strong>Bond</strong> Portfolio 115Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 115Numerical Example 118Questions 121CHAPTER 7Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss Distribution 123Monte Carlo Methods 123<strong>Credit</strong> Loss Simulation 125Generat<strong>in</strong>g Correlated Asset Returns 126Inferr<strong>in</strong>g Implied <strong>Credit</strong> Rat<strong>in</strong>g 128Comput<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> Loss 128Comput<strong>in</strong>g Expected Loss and Unexpected Loss 130Importance Sampl<strong>in</strong>g 131Tail <strong>Risk</strong> Measures 132<strong>Credit</strong> Value at <strong>Risk</strong> 132Expected Shortfall <strong>Risk</strong> 133Numerical Results 135Questions 138CHAPTER 8Relax<strong>in</strong>g the Normal Distribution Assumption 139Motivation 140Student’s t Distribution 140Probability Density Function 142Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 142Default Mode 143Migration Mode 145Loss Simulation 149Appendix 151Questions 154


viiiCONTENTSCHAPTER 9<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 155Relative <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures 156Marg<strong>in</strong>al <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Contribution 160Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Report 162<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g Dur<strong>in</strong>g Economic Contractions 165Portfolio Market <strong>Risk</strong> Report 168<strong>Risk</strong> Guidel<strong>in</strong>es 169Performance Attribution 170A Simple Attribution Model 172Questions 175CHAPTER 10Portfolio Optimization 177Portfolio Selection Techniques 178Benefits of a Quantitative Approach 179Optimization Methods 180L<strong>in</strong>ear Programm<strong>in</strong>g 180Quadratic Programm<strong>in</strong>g 181Nonl<strong>in</strong>ear Programm<strong>in</strong>g 181Practical Difficulties 182Portfolio Construction 183Sett<strong>in</strong>g Up the Constra<strong>in</strong>ts 185The Optimization Problem 187Optimal Portfolio Composition 188Robustness of Portfolio Composition 191Portfolio Rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g 191Identify<strong>in</strong>g Sell Transactions 192Identify<strong>in</strong>g the Rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g Trades 194Numerical Results 197Devil <strong>in</strong> the Parameters: A Case Study 199<strong>Risk</strong> Reduction 203Questions 204CHAPTER 11Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 206Introduction to CDOs 207Balance Sheet versus Arbitrage CDOs 207Cash Flow versus Market Value CDOs 209Cash versus Synthetic CDOs 210Investor Motivations 210


ContentsixAnatomy of a CDO Transaction 211Capital Structure 211How the Transaction Evolves 213Parties to a CDO 214Structural Protections 215Major Sources of <strong>Risk</strong> <strong>in</strong> CDOs 218Interest Rate <strong>Risk</strong> 218Liquidity <strong>Risk</strong> 219Ramp-Up <strong>Risk</strong> 219Re<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>Risk</strong> 219Prepayment <strong>Risk</strong> 220Asset Manager <strong>Risk</strong> 220Rat<strong>in</strong>g a CDO Transaction 221Moody’s Method 222Standard & Poor’s Method 226Method of Fitch Rat<strong>in</strong>gs 228Tradable <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Baskets 230Ma<strong>in</strong> Features of Tracers 231Portfolio Composition and <strong>Risk</strong> Characteristics 231Implied <strong>Credit</strong> Rat<strong>in</strong>g 233Questions 236SOLUTIONS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 237INDEX 262


ForewordSome of the greatest advances <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ance over the past two to threedecades have come <strong>in</strong> the field of risk management. Theoretical developmentshave enabled us to disaggregate risk elements and thus better identifyand price risk factors. New <strong>in</strong>struments have been created to enable practitionersto more actively manage their risk profiles by shedd<strong>in</strong>g those exposuresthey are not well placed to hold while reta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g (or leverag<strong>in</strong>g) thosethat reflect their comparative advantage. The practical consequence is thatthe market for risk management <strong>in</strong>struments has grown exponentially.These <strong>in</strong>struments are now actively used by all categories of <strong>in</strong>stitution andportfolio managers.Partly as a result of this, the bus<strong>in</strong>ess of portfolio management hasbecome enormously more competitive. Fall<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest rates have motivatedclients to be more demand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> their search for yield. But it would probablyhave happened anyway. Institutional <strong>in</strong>vestors are cont<strong>in</strong>uously seek<strong>in</strong>ga more efficient risk–return comb<strong>in</strong>ation as well as decid<strong>in</strong>g exactly whereon the risk–return frontier they wish to position themselves. All thisrequires constant ref<strong>in</strong>ement of portfolio management techniques to keepup with evolv<strong>in</strong>g best practice.The basic <strong>in</strong>sights beh<strong>in</strong>d the new techniques of risk managementdepend on mathematical <strong>in</strong>novations. The sophistication of the emerg<strong>in</strong>gmethodology has important strengths, but it also has limitations. The keystrength is analytic rigor. This rigor, coupled with the computational powerof modern <strong>in</strong>formation technology, allows portfolio managers to quicklyassess the risk characteristics of an <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong>strument as well as measureits impact on the overall risk structure of a portfolio.The opposite side of the co<strong>in</strong> to analytic rigor is the complexity of themodels used. This complexity opens a gap between the statistical measurementof risk and the economic <strong>in</strong>tuition that lies beh<strong>in</strong>d it. This would notmatter too much if models could always be relied on to produce the “right’’results. After all, we do not need to understand <strong>in</strong>ternal combustion orhydraulic brak<strong>in</strong>g to drive a car. Most of the time, of course, models do producemore or less the right answers. However, <strong>in</strong> times of stress, we becomeaware of two key limitations. First, because statistical applications must bebased on available data, they implicitly assume that the past is a good guideto the future. In extreme circumstances, that assumption may break down.xi


xiiFOREWORDSecond, portfolio model<strong>in</strong>g techniques implicitly assume low transactioncosts (i.e., cont<strong>in</strong>uous market liquidity). Experience has taught (notably <strong>in</strong>the 1998 episode) that this assumption must also be used carefully.<strong>Credit</strong> risk model<strong>in</strong>g presents added complications. The diversity ofevents (macro and micro) that can affect credit quality is substantial.Moreover, correlations among different credits are complex and can varyover time. Statistical techniques are powerful tools for captur<strong>in</strong>g the lessonsof past experience. In the case of credit experience, however, we mustbe particularly m<strong>in</strong>dful of the possibility that the future will be differentfrom the past.Where do these reflections lead? First, to the conclusion that portfoliomanagers need to use all the tools at their disposal to improve their understand<strong>in</strong>gof the forces shap<strong>in</strong>g portfolio returns. The statistical techniquesdescribed <strong>in</strong> this book are <strong>in</strong>dispensable <strong>in</strong> this connection. Second, thatsenior management of <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>vestors and their clients must not treatrisk management models as a black box whose output can be uncriticallyaccepted. They must strive to understand the properties of the models usedand the assumptions <strong>in</strong>volved. In this way, they will better judge how muchreliance to place on model output and how much judgmental modificationis required.Srichander Ramaswamy’s book responds to both these po<strong>in</strong>ts. A carefulread<strong>in</strong>g (which, admittedly, to the un<strong>in</strong>itiated may not be easy) shouldgive the reader a better grasp of the practice of portfolio management andits reliance on statistical model<strong>in</strong>g techniques. Through a better understand<strong>in</strong>gof the techniques <strong>in</strong>volved, portfolio managers and their clientswill become better <strong>in</strong>formed and more efficient players <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>ancial system.This is good for efficiency and stability alike.Sir Andrew CrockettFormer General ManagerBank for International Settlements


PrefaceCurrently, credit risk is a hot topic. This is partly due to the fact that thereis much confusion and misunderstand<strong>in</strong>g concern<strong>in</strong>g how to measureand manage credit risk <strong>in</strong> a practical sett<strong>in</strong>g. This confusion stems ma<strong>in</strong>lyfrom the nature of credit risk: It is the risk of a rare event occurr<strong>in</strong>g, whichmay not have been observed <strong>in</strong> the past. Quantify<strong>in</strong>g someth<strong>in</strong>g that hasnot been previously observed requires us<strong>in</strong>g models and mak<strong>in</strong>g severalassumptions. The precise nature of the assumptions and the types of modelsused to quantify credit risk can vary substantially, lead<strong>in</strong>g to more confusionand misunderstand<strong>in</strong>g and, <strong>in</strong> many cases, practitioners come to mistrustthe models themselves.The best I could have done to avoid add<strong>in</strong>g further confusion to thissubject is to not write a book whose central theme is credit risk. However,as a practitioner, I went through a frustrat<strong>in</strong>g experience while try<strong>in</strong>g toadapt exist<strong>in</strong>g credit risk model<strong>in</strong>g techniques to solve a seem<strong>in</strong>gly mundanepractical problem: Measure and manage the relative credit risk of acorporate bond portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st its benchmark. To do this, one does notrequire the technical expertise of a rocket scientist to figure out how to pricecomplex credit derivatives or compute risk-neutral default <strong>in</strong>tensities fromempirically observed default probabilities. Nevertheless, I found the taskquite challeng<strong>in</strong>g. This book grew out of my conviction that the exist<strong>in</strong>g literatureon credit risk does not address an important practical problem <strong>in</strong>the area of bond portfolio management.But that is only part of the story. The real impetus to writ<strong>in</strong>g this bookgrew out of my professional correspondence with Frank Fabozzi. After onesuch correspondence, Frank came up with a suggestion: Why not write abook on this important topic? I found this suggestion difficult to turn down,especially because I owe much of my knowledge of bond portfolio managementto his writ<strong>in</strong>gs. Writ<strong>in</strong>g this book would not have been possiblewithout his encouragement, support, and guidance. It has been both apleasure and a privilege to work closely with Frank on this project.While writ<strong>in</strong>g this book, I tried to follow the style that sells best ontrad<strong>in</strong>g floors and <strong>in</strong> management meet<strong>in</strong>gs: Keep it simple. However, I mayhave failed miserably <strong>in</strong> this. As the project progressed, I realized that quantificationof credit risk requires mathematical tools that are usually nottaught at the undergraduate level of a nonscience discipl<strong>in</strong>e. On the positivexiii


xivPREFACEside, however, I strove to f<strong>in</strong>d the right balance between theory and practiceand to make assumptions that are relevant <strong>in</strong> a practical sett<strong>in</strong>g.Despite its technical content, I hope this book will be of <strong>in</strong>terest to awide audience <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>dustry. Institutional <strong>in</strong>vestors will f<strong>in</strong>d thebook useful for identify<strong>in</strong>g potential risk guidel<strong>in</strong>es they can impose ontheir corporate bond portfolio mandates. <strong>Risk</strong> managers will f<strong>in</strong>d the riskmeasurement framework offers an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g alternative to exist<strong>in</strong>g methodsfor monitor<strong>in</strong>g and report<strong>in</strong>g the risks <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfolio.Portfolio managers will f<strong>in</strong>d the portfolio optimization techniques providehelpful aids to portfolio selection and rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g processes. F<strong>in</strong>ancial eng<strong>in</strong>eersand quantitative analysts will benefit considerably from the technicalcoverage of the topics and the scope the book provides to develop trad<strong>in</strong>gtools to support the corporate bond portfolio management bus<strong>in</strong>ess.This book can also serve as a one-semester graduate text for a courseon corporate bond portfolio management <strong>in</strong> quantitative f<strong>in</strong>ance. I haveused parts of this book to teach a one-quarter course on fixed <strong>in</strong>come portfoliomanagement at the University of Lausanne for master’s-level students<strong>in</strong> bank<strong>in</strong>g and f<strong>in</strong>ance. To make the book student-friendly, I have <strong>in</strong>cludedend-of-chapter questions and solutions.Writ<strong>in</strong>g this book has taken substantial time away from my family. Ithank my wife, Esther, for her support and patience dur<strong>in</strong>g this project, myfirst son, Björn, for forgo<strong>in</strong>g bedtime stories so that I could work on thebook, and my second son, Ricardo, for sleep<strong>in</strong>g through the night while Iwas busy writ<strong>in</strong>g the book. I am also very grateful for the support of themanagement of the Bank for International Settlements, who k<strong>in</strong>dly gave methe permission to publish this book. In particular, I would like to thank BobSleeper for his encouragement and support, and for provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>sightfulcomments on the orig<strong>in</strong>al manuscript of this book. F<strong>in</strong>ally, I wish to expressmy gratitude to Pamela van Giessen, Todd Tedesco, and Jennifer MacDonaldat John Wiley for their assistance dur<strong>in</strong>g this project.The views expressed <strong>in</strong> this book are m<strong>in</strong>e, and do not necessarilyreflect the views of the Bank for International Settlements.Srichander Ramaswamy


CHAPTER 1IntroductionMOTIVATIONMost recent books on credit risk management focus on manag<strong>in</strong>g creditrisk from a middle office perspective. That is, measur<strong>in</strong>g and controll<strong>in</strong>gcredit risk, implement<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternal models for capital allocation for creditrisk, comput<strong>in</strong>g risk-adjusted performance measures, and comput<strong>in</strong>g regulatorycapital for credit risk are normally the topics dealt with <strong>in</strong> detail.However, seen from a front office perspective, the need to manage creditrisk prudently is driven more by the desire to meet a return target than therequirement to ensure that the risk limits are with<strong>in</strong> agreed guidel<strong>in</strong>es. Thisis particularly the case for portfolio managers, whose task may be to eitherreplicate or outperform a benchmark compris<strong>in</strong>g corporate bonds. In perform<strong>in</strong>gthis task, portfolio managers often have to strike the right balancebetween be<strong>in</strong>g a trader and be<strong>in</strong>g a risk manager at the same time.In order to manage the risks of the corporate bond portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st agiven benchmark, one requires tools for risk measurement. Unlike <strong>in</strong> thecase of a government bond portfolio, where the dom<strong>in</strong>ant risk is marketrisk, the risk <strong>in</strong> a portfolio consist<strong>in</strong>g of corporate bonds is primarily creditrisk. In the portfolio management context, standard practice is to measurethe risk relative to its benchmark. Although measures to quantify themarket risk of a bond portfolio relative to its benchmark are well known,no standard measures exist to quantify the relative credit risk of a corporatebond portfolio versus its benchmark. As a consequence, there are noclear guidel<strong>in</strong>es as to how the risk exposures <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfoliocan be quantified and presented so that <strong>in</strong>formed decisions can be made andlimits for permissible risk exposures can be set. The lack of proper standardsfor risk report<strong>in</strong>g on corporate bond portfolio mandates makes thetask of compliance monitor<strong>in</strong>g difficult. Moreover, it is also difficult to verifywhether the portfolio manager acted <strong>in</strong> the best <strong>in</strong>terest of the client and<strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the spirit of the manager’s fiduciary responsibilities.The lack of proper risk measures for quantify<strong>in</strong>g the dom<strong>in</strong>ant risks ofthe corporate bond portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st its benchmark also makes the task of1


2 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSchoos<strong>in</strong>g the right bonds to hold <strong>in</strong> the portfolio rather difficult. As thenumber of issuers <strong>in</strong> the benchmark <strong>in</strong>creases, identify<strong>in</strong>g a subset ofbonds from the benchmark composition becomes cumbersome even withthe help of several credit analysts. This is because corporate bond portfoliomanagement concerns itself with efficient diversification of the creditrisk through prudently select<strong>in</strong>g which bond obligors to <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong> theportfolio. In general, it has less to do with the identification of good creditsseen <strong>in</strong> isolation. The diversification efficiency is measured relative tothe level of credit diversification present <strong>in</strong> the benchmark portfolio.Select<strong>in</strong>g bonds such that the aggregate risks of the corporate portfolio arelower than those of the benchmark while simultaneously ensur<strong>in</strong>g that theportfolio offers scope for improved returns over those of the benchmark<strong>in</strong>variably requires the use of quantitative techniques to drive the portfolioselection process.This book was written to address these difficulties with respect to manag<strong>in</strong>ga corporate bond portfolio. In do<strong>in</strong>g this, I have tried to strike a reasonablebalance between the practical relevance of the topics presented andthe level of mathematical sophistication required to follow the discussions.Work<strong>in</strong>g for several years closely with traders and portfolio managers hashelped me understand the difficulties encountered when quantitative methodsare used to solve practical problems. Invariably, many of the practical difficultiestend to be overlooked <strong>in</strong> a more academic sett<strong>in</strong>g, which <strong>in</strong> turncauses the proposed quantitative methods to lose practical relevance. I havemade a strong attempt to not fall <strong>in</strong>to this trap while writ<strong>in</strong>g this book. However,many of the ideas presented are still untested <strong>in</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g real money.SUMMARY OF THE BOOKAlthough this book’s orientation is an applied one, some of the conceptspresented here rely substantially on quantitative models. Despite this, mostof the topics covered are easily accessible to readers with a basic knowledgeof mathematics. In a nutshell, this book is primarily about comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>grisk management concepts with portfolio construction techniques andexplores the role quantitative methods can play <strong>in</strong> this <strong>in</strong>tegration processwith particular emphasis on corporate bond portfolio management. Thetopics covered are organized <strong>in</strong> a cohesive manner, so sequential read<strong>in</strong>g isrecommended. Briefly, the topics covered are as follows.Chapter 2 covers basic concepts <strong>in</strong> probability theory and l<strong>in</strong>ear algebrathat are required to follow certa<strong>in</strong> sections <strong>in</strong> this book. The <strong>in</strong>tentionof this chapter is to fill <strong>in</strong> a limited number of possible gaps <strong>in</strong> the reader’sknowledge <strong>in</strong> these areas. Readers familiar with probability theory and l<strong>in</strong>earalgebra could skip this chapter.


Introduction 3Chapter 3 provides a brief <strong>in</strong>troduction to the corporate bond market.<strong>Bond</strong> collateralization and corporate bond <strong>in</strong>vestment risks are briefly discussed.This chapter also gives an overview of the practical difficultiesencountered <strong>in</strong> trad<strong>in</strong>g corporate as opposed to government bonds, theimportant role corporate bonds play <strong>in</strong> buffer<strong>in</strong>g the impact of a f<strong>in</strong>ancialcrisis, the relative market size and historical performance of corporatebonds. The chapter concludes by argu<strong>in</strong>g that the corporate bond market isan <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g asset class for the reserves portfolios of central banks and forpension funds.Chapter 4 offers a brief review of market risk measures associated withchanges to <strong>in</strong>terest rates, implied volatility, and exchange rates. Interest raterisk exposure <strong>in</strong> this book is restricted to the price sensitivity result<strong>in</strong>g fromchanges to the swap curve of the currency <strong>in</strong> which the corporate bond isissued. Changes to the bond yield that cannot be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by changes tothe swap curve are attributed to credit risk. Tak<strong>in</strong>g this approach results <strong>in</strong>considerable simplification to market risk model<strong>in</strong>g because yield curves donot have to be computed for different credit-rat<strong>in</strong>g categories.Chapter 5 <strong>in</strong>troduces various factors that are important determ<strong>in</strong>antsof credit risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond and describes standard methods used toestimate them at the security level. It also highlights the differences <strong>in</strong> conceptualapproaches used to model credit risk and the data limitationsassociated with parameter specification and estimation. Subsequently,quantification of credit risk at the security level is discussed <strong>in</strong> considerabledetail.Chapter 6 covers the topic of portfolio credit risk. In this chapter, thenotion of correlated credit events is <strong>in</strong>troduced; <strong>in</strong>direct methods that canbe used to estimate credit correlations are discussed. An approach todeterm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the approximate asset return correlation between obligors isalso outl<strong>in</strong>ed. F<strong>in</strong>ally, analytical approaches for comput<strong>in</strong>g portfolio creditrisk under the default mode and the migration mode are dealt with <strong>in</strong>detail assum<strong>in</strong>g that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is multivariatenormal.Chapter 7 deals with the computation of portfolio credit risk us<strong>in</strong>g asimulation approach. In tak<strong>in</strong>g this approach, it is once aga<strong>in</strong> assumedthat the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is multivariate normal. Consider<strong>in</strong>gthat the distribution of credit losses is highly skewed with a long, fattail, two tail risk measures for credit risk, namely credit value at risk andexpected shortfall risk, are <strong>in</strong>troduced. The estimation of these tail riskmeasures from the simulated data is also <strong>in</strong>dicated.In Chapter 8, the assumption that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returnsis multivariate normal is relaxed. Specifically, it is assumed that the jo<strong>in</strong>tdistribution of asset returns is multivariate t-distributed. Under thisassumption, changes to the schemes required to compute various credit


4 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSrisk measures of <strong>in</strong>terest us<strong>in</strong>g analytical and simulation approaches arediscussed.Chapter 9 develops a framework for report<strong>in</strong>g the credit risk and marketrisk of a corporate bond portfolio that is managed aga<strong>in</strong>st a benchmark.To highlight the impact of model errors on the aggregate risk measurescomputed, risk report generation under different model<strong>in</strong>g assumptions and<strong>in</strong>put parameter values is presented. A simple performance attributionmodel for identify<strong>in</strong>g the sources of excess return aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark isalso developed <strong>in</strong> this chapter.Chapter 10 beg<strong>in</strong>s with a brief <strong>in</strong>troduction to portfolio optimizationtechniques and the practical difficulties that arise <strong>in</strong> us<strong>in</strong>g such techniquesfor portfolio selection. This is followed by the formulation of an optimizationproblem for construct<strong>in</strong>g a bond portfolio that offers improvedrisk-adjusted returns compared to the benchmark. Subsequently, an optimizationproblem for portfolio rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g is formulated <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>gturnover constra<strong>in</strong>ts so that the trade recommendations are implementable.F<strong>in</strong>ally, a case study is performed us<strong>in</strong>g an actual market <strong>in</strong>dex to illustratethe impact of alternative parametrizations of the credit risk model on theoptimal portfolio’s composition.Chapter 11 provides a brief overview of collateralized debt obligationsand tradeable corporate bond baskets and discusses how the credit risks ofsuch structured products can be analyzed us<strong>in</strong>g the techniques presented <strong>in</strong>this book. This chapter also provides a methodology for <strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>g theimplied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of such structured products.A number of numerical examples are given <strong>in</strong> every chapter to illustratethe concepts presented and l<strong>in</strong>k theory with practice. All numericalresults presented <strong>in</strong> this book were generated by cod<strong>in</strong>g the numerical algorithms<strong>in</strong> C language. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, I made extensive use of Numerical AlgorithmsGroup (NAG) C libraries to facilitate the numerical computations.


CHAPTER 2Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>ariesThe purpose of this chapter is to provide a concise treatment of the conceptsfrom probability theory and l<strong>in</strong>ear algebra that are useful <strong>in</strong> connectionwith the material <strong>in</strong> this book. The coverage of these topics is not<strong>in</strong>tended to be rigorous, but is given to fill <strong>in</strong> a limited number of possiblegaps <strong>in</strong> the reader’s knowledge. Readers familiar with probability theoryand l<strong>in</strong>ear algebra may wish to skip this chapter.PROBABILITY THEORYIn its simplest <strong>in</strong>terpretation, probability theory is the branch of mathematicsthat deals with calculat<strong>in</strong>g the likelihood of a given event’s occurrence,which is expressed as a number between 0 and 1. For <strong>in</strong>stance, whatis the likelihood that the number 3 will show up when a die is rolled? Inanother experiment, one might be <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the jo<strong>in</strong>t likelihood of thenumber 3 show<strong>in</strong>g up when a die is rolled and the head show<strong>in</strong>g up whena co<strong>in</strong> is tossed. Seek<strong>in</strong>g answers to these types of questions leads to thestudy of distribution and jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution functions. (The answers to thequestions posed here are 1/6 and 1/12, respectively). Applications <strong>in</strong> whichrepeated experiments are performed and properties of the sequence of randomoutcomes are analyzed lead to the study of stochastic processes. In thissection, I discuss distribution functions and stochastic processes.Characteriz<strong>in</strong>g Probability DistributionsProbability distribution functions play an important role <strong>in</strong> characteriz<strong>in</strong>guncerta<strong>in</strong> quantities that one encounters <strong>in</strong> daily life. In f<strong>in</strong>ance, one canth<strong>in</strong>k of the uncerta<strong>in</strong> quantities as represent<strong>in</strong>g the future price of a stockor a bond. One may also consider the price return from hold<strong>in</strong>g a stockover a specified period of time as be<strong>in</strong>g an uncerta<strong>in</strong> quantity. In probabilitytheory, this uncerta<strong>in</strong> quantity is known as a random variable. Thus, thedaily or monthly returns on a stock or a bond held can be thought of as5


6 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSrandom variables. Associated with each value a random variable can take isa probability, which can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as the relative frequency of occurrenceof this value. The set of all such probabilities form the probability distributionof the random variable. The probability distribution for a randomvariable X is usually represented by its cumulative distribution function.This function gives the probability that X is less than or equal to x:The probability distribution for X may also be represented by its probabilitydensity function, which is the derivative of the cumulative distributionfunction:A random variable and its distribution are called discrete if X can takeonly a f<strong>in</strong>ite number of values and cont<strong>in</strong>uous if the random variable cantake an <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ite number of values. For discrete distributions, the densityfunction is referred to as the probability mass function and is denoted p(x).It refers to the probability of the event X x occurr<strong>in</strong>g. Examples of discretedistributions are the outcomes of roll<strong>in</strong>g a die or toss<strong>in</strong>g a co<strong>in</strong>. Therandom variable describ<strong>in</strong>g price returns on a stock or a bond, on the otherhand, has a cont<strong>in</strong>uous distribution.Knowledge of the distribution function of a random variable providesall <strong>in</strong>formation on the properties of the random variable <strong>in</strong> question. Commonpractice, however, is to characterize the distribution function us<strong>in</strong>g themoments of the distribution which captures the important properties of thedistribution. The best known is the first moment of the distribution, betterknown by the term mean of the distribution. The first moments of a cont<strong>in</strong>uousand a discrete distribution are given, respectively, byandF(x) P(X x)f(x) dF(x)dx qq ani1xf(x)dxx i p(x i )The mean of a distribution is also known by the term expected value and isdenoted E(X). It is common to refer to E(X) as the expected value of therandom variable X. If the moments are taken by subtract<strong>in</strong>g the mean of


Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 7the distribution from the random variable, then they are known as centralmoments. The second central moment represents the variance of the distributionand is given bys 2 qqs 2 ani1(x ) 2 f(x)dx (cont<strong>in</strong>uous distribution)(x i ) 2 p(x i ) (discrete distribution)Follow<strong>in</strong>g the def<strong>in</strong>ition of the expected value of a random variable, thevariance of the distribution can be represented <strong>in</strong> the expected value notationas E[(X ) 2 ]. The square root of the variance is referred to as thestandard deviation of the distribution. The variance or standard deviationof a distribution gives an <strong>in</strong>dication of the dispersion of the distributionabout the mean.More <strong>in</strong>sight <strong>in</strong>to the shape of the distribution function can be ga<strong>in</strong>edby specify<strong>in</strong>g two other parameters of the distribution. These parametersare the skewness and the kurtosis of the distribution. For a cont<strong>in</strong>uous distribution,the skewness and the kurtosis are def<strong>in</strong>ed as follows:skewness qqkurtosis qq(x ) 3 f(x)dx(x ) 4 f(x)dxIf the distribution is symmetric around the mean, then the skewness is zero.Kurtosis describes the “peakedness” or “flatness” of a distribution. A leptokurticdistribution is one <strong>in</strong> which more observations are clusteredaround the mean of the distribution and <strong>in</strong> the tail region. This is the case,for <strong>in</strong>stance, when one observes the returns on stock prices.In connection with value at risk calculations, one requires the def<strong>in</strong>itionof the quantile of a distribution. The pth quantile of a distribution, denotedX p , is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the value such that there is a probability p that the actualvalue of the random variable is less than this value:X pp P(X X p ) f(x)dxq


8 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSIf the probability is expressed <strong>in</strong> percent, the quantile is referred to as a percentile.For <strong>in</strong>stance, to compute value at risk at the 90 percent level of confidence,one has to compute the 10th percentile of the return distribution.Useful Probability DistributionsIn this section, I <strong>in</strong>troduce different probability distributions that arise <strong>in</strong>connection with the quantification of credit risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfolio.Formulas are given for the probability density function and the correspond<strong>in</strong>gmean and variance of the distribution.Normal Distribution A normally distributed random variable takes valuesover the entire range of real numbers. The parameters of the distributionare directly related to the mean and the variance of the distribution, and theskewness is zero due to the symmetry of the distribution. Normal distributionsare used to characterize the distribution of returns on assets, such asstocks and bonds. The probability density function of a normally distributedrandom variable is given byf(x) 122ps(x )2exp a b2s 2If the mean is zero and the standard deviation is one, the normally distributedrandom variable is referred to as a standardized normal random variable.Bernoulli Distribution A fundamental issue <strong>in</strong> credit risk is the determ<strong>in</strong>ationof the probability of a credit event. By the very nature of this event, historicaldata on which to base such assessments are limited. Event probabilitiesare represented by a discrete zero–one random variable. Such a randomvariable X is said to follow a Bernoulli distribution with probability massfunction given byp(x) e 1 p if X 0p if X 1where p is the parameter of the distribution. The outcome X 1 denotes theoccurrence of an event and the outcome X 0 denotes the nonoccurrence ofthe event. The event could represent the default of an obligor <strong>in</strong> the contextof credit risk. The Bernoulli random variable is completely characterized byits parameter p and has an expected value of p and a variance of p(1 p).Gamma Distribution The gamma distribution is characterized by two parameters,0 and 0, which are referred to as the shape parameter and


Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 9the scale parameter, respectively. Although gamma distributions are notused directly for credit risk computations, special cases of the gamma distributionplay a role when the normal distribution assumption for assetreturns is relaxed. The probability density function of the gamma distributionis given by1() x 1 e x/ , 0 x qf(x) e 0, x 0where() qx 1 e x dx0The mean and the variance of the gamma distribution are and 2 ,respectively. The special case <strong>in</strong> which n/2 (where n is a positive <strong>in</strong>teger)and 2 leads to a chi-square-distributed random variable with ndegrees of freedom.Beta Distribution The beta distribution provides a very flexible means of represent<strong>in</strong>gvariability over a fixed range. The two-parameter beta distributiontakes nonzero values <strong>in</strong> the range between 0 and 1. The flexibility ofthe distribution encourages its empirical use <strong>in</strong> a wide range of applications.In credit risk applications, the beta distribution is used to model the recoveryrate process on defaulted bonds. The probability density function of thebeta distribution is given by( )() () x 1 (1 x) 1 , 0 x 1f(x, , ) e0, otherwisewhere 0, 0, and () is the gamma function. The mean and varianceof the beta distribution are given, respectively, byands 2 ( ) 2 (1)


10 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSUniform Distribution The uniform distribution provides one of the simplestmeans of represent<strong>in</strong>g uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty. Its use is appropriate <strong>in</strong> situations whereone can identify the range of possible values, but is unable to decide whichvalues with<strong>in</strong> this range are more likely to occur than others. The probabilitydensity function of a uniformly distributed random variable def<strong>in</strong>ed<strong>in</strong> the range between a and b is given byf(x) 1b a ,a x bThe mean and the variance of the distribution are given, respectively, byand a b2s 2 (b a)212In the context of credit risk quantification, one can use the uniform distributionto describe the recovery rate process on defaulted bonds as opposedto describ<strong>in</strong>g this by a beta distribution. This is because when one simulatesthe credit loss for a portfolio, use of the beta distribution often generatesrecovery values that can be close to the par value of the bond. Inpractice, such recovery values are rarely realized. Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the recoveryvalues from a uniform distribution can limit the range of possible recoveryvalues.For purpose of illustration, consider a recovery value of 47 percent anda volatility of recovery value of 25 percent (these values reflect the empiricalestimates for unsecured bonds). The correspond<strong>in</strong>g value of the parametersof the uniform distribution are a 0.037 and b 0.903. When us<strong>in</strong>gthese parameter values to simulate recovery values, the maximum recoveryvalue is limited to 90 percent of the par amount of the bond. If one choosesthe recovery rate volatility to be 22 percent rather than 25 percent, then therecovery values <strong>in</strong> a simulation run are restricted to lie <strong>in</strong> the range 9 percentto 85 percent of the par amount of the bond.Jo<strong>in</strong>t DistributionsThe study of jo<strong>in</strong>t probability distributions arises if there is more than onerandom variable to deal with. For <strong>in</strong>stance, one may want to study howthe default of one obligor <strong>in</strong>fluences the default of another obligor. In thiscase, one is <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the jo<strong>in</strong>t probability that both obligors will


Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 11default over a given time period. To exam<strong>in</strong>e this, one needs to def<strong>in</strong>e jo<strong>in</strong>tprobability distribution functions. Specifically, the jo<strong>in</strong>t probability distributionof the random variables X and Y is characterized by the follow<strong>in</strong>gquantity:F(x, y) P(X x, Y y)The right-hand side of this equation represents the jo<strong>in</strong>t probability that Xis less than x and Y is less than y. The correspond<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>t density functionis given byf(x, y) 02 F(x, y)0x 0yThe two random variables are said to be <strong>in</strong>dependent if the jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionfunction can be written as the product of the marg<strong>in</strong>al distributions asgiven byF(x, y) F(x)F(y)When deal<strong>in</strong>g with more than one random variable, an importantattribute of <strong>in</strong>terest is the correlation between the random variables. Correlationdeterm<strong>in</strong>es the degree of dependence between the random variables<strong>in</strong> question. If the random variables are <strong>in</strong>dependent, then the correlationbetween the random variables is zero.The def<strong>in</strong>ition of the coefficient of correlation between two randomvariables requires the <strong>in</strong>troduction of another term, called the covariance.The covariance between two random variables X and Y is by def<strong>in</strong>ition thefollow<strong>in</strong>g quantity:s XY E[(X X )(Y Y )] E(XY) E(X)E(Y)Here, X and Y are the expected values of the random variables X and Y,respectively. If X and Y denote the standard deviations of the randomvariables X and Y, respectively, then the coefficient of correlation betweenthe two random variables is given byr XY s XYs X s YIf the random variables are <strong>in</strong>dependent, then the expected value of theirproduct is equal to the product of their expected values, that is,E(XY) E(X)E(Y)


12 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSAs mentioned, <strong>in</strong> this case the correlation between the two randomvariables is zero, or equivalently, the random variables are uncorrelated. Itis useful to note here that if two normally distributed random variables areuncorrelated, then the random variables are also <strong>in</strong>dependent. This is nottrue for random variables that have a different distribution.Stochastic ProcessesThe probability distribution functions discussed so far arise <strong>in</strong> the contextof isolated experiments such as roll<strong>in</strong>g a die or toss<strong>in</strong>g a co<strong>in</strong>. In such experiments,a probability distribution function provides <strong>in</strong>formation on the possiblevalues the random outcome of the experiment can take. However, ifone is <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> study<strong>in</strong>g the properties of the sequence of random outcomeswhen the experiment is performed repeatedly, one enters <strong>in</strong>to thedoma<strong>in</strong> of stochastic processes. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the evolution of the price of astock over time can be thought of as a stochastic process. At any given po<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong> time, the price of the stock can be regarded as a random variable.This price process of a stock is usually referred to as a cont<strong>in</strong>uous-timestochastic process. In such a process, both time and the values the randomvariable can take are <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>itely many. Consider roll<strong>in</strong>g a die; the possibleoutcomes are limited to a set of six values. In this case, the stochasticprocess is referred to as a discrete-state stochastic process. If the timedimension is also allowed to take on only a discrete set of values, theprocess is referred to as a discrete-time, discrete-state stochastic process.In connection with a stochastic process, one may be <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>ferences based on the past values of the stochastic process that wasobserved. This leads to the topic of conditional distributions. In the case ofroll<strong>in</strong>g a die, observ<strong>in</strong>g the outcomes dur<strong>in</strong>g a sequence of rolls providesno <strong>in</strong>formation on what the outcome of the next roll will be. In otherwords, the conditional and unconditional distributions are identical andthe sequence of experiments can be termed <strong>in</strong>dependent. This is an extremeexample where the past has no <strong>in</strong>fluence on the future outcomes of theexperiment.Markov Cha<strong>in</strong>s An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g variant to the forego<strong>in</strong>g case is when theexperiment’s next outcome depends only on its last outcome. A stochasticprocess that exhibits this property is known as a Markov process. Depend<strong>in</strong>gon whether the values the Markov process can take are restricted to af<strong>in</strong>ite set or not, one can dist<strong>in</strong>guish between discrete-state and cont<strong>in</strong>uousstateMarkov processes. Furthermore, if the time <strong>in</strong>stants at which weobserve a discrete-state Markov process are also restricted to a f<strong>in</strong>ite set,then this Markov process is known as a Markov cha<strong>in</strong>. Markov cha<strong>in</strong>s areused <strong>in</strong> the model<strong>in</strong>g of rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations of obligors.


Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 13To provide a formal def<strong>in</strong>ition of Markov cha<strong>in</strong>s, consider a discretetimestochastic process, denoted {X n , n 0}, which takes values from af<strong>in</strong>ite set S called the state space of the process. The members of this seti S satisfy the property P(X n i) 0 for some n 0, where P() denotesthe probability of an event occurr<strong>in</strong>g. The process {X n , n 0} is called adiscrete-time Markov cha<strong>in</strong> if it has the follow<strong>in</strong>g property for any n 0:P(X n1 i n1 |X n i n ,,X 0 i 0 ) P(X n1 i n1 |X n i n )This conditional probability is referred to as the transition probability. Ifthe transition probability is <strong>in</strong>dependent of n, then the process {X n , n 0}is called a homogeneous Markov cha<strong>in</strong>. For a homogenous Markov cha<strong>in</strong>,the one-step transition probability from state i S to state j S is denotedbyP(X n1 j S|X n i S) p ijIf there are m states <strong>in</strong> S, then the forego<strong>in</strong>g def<strong>in</strong>ition gives rise to m mtransition probabilities. These transition probabilities form the elements ofan m m matrix known as the probability transition matrix. I discuss theproperties of this matrix <strong>in</strong> the section on l<strong>in</strong>ear algebra under the topicMarkov matrix.LINEAR ALGEBRAL<strong>in</strong>ear algebra, as it concerns us <strong>in</strong> this book, is a study of the properties ofmatrices. A matrix is a rectangular array of numbers, and these numbers areknown as the elements of the matrix. By an m n matrix one means amatrix with m rows and n columns. In the special case where n 1, thematrix collapses to a column vector. If m n, then the matrix is referred toas a square matrix. In this book, we are only concerned with square matrices.For purpose of illustration, a 3 3 matrix A is represented asa 11 a 12 a 13A £ a 21 a 22 a 23 §a 31 a 32 a 33It is also common to represent a matrix with elements a ij as [a ij ]. If the elementsof the matrix A are such that a ij a ji for every i and j, then the matrixis referred to as a symmetric matrix. The addition of two n n matrices Aand B results <strong>in</strong> an n n matrix C whose elements are as follows:c ij a ij b ij ,i, j 1,2, ... , n


14 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSThe multiplication of an n n matrix by an n 1 vector results <strong>in</strong> a vectorof dimension n 1. For example, if A is an n n matrix and x is ann 1 vector, the product Ax gives rise to an n 1 vector b whose elementsare as follows:b i anj1a ij x j , i 1,2, . . . ,nMatrices and vectors are very useful because they make it possible to performcomplex calculations us<strong>in</strong>g compact notation. I now <strong>in</strong>troduce variousconcepts that are commonly used <strong>in</strong> connection with vectors andmatrices.Properties of VectorsIf x is a vector, the product x T x is known as the <strong>in</strong>ner product and is ascalar quantity. If x T x 1, then the vector x is referred to as a unit vectoror normalized vector. The quantity ||x|| 2x T x is called the 2-norm orsimply the norm of the vector. Any vector can be normalized by divid<strong>in</strong>g theelements of the vector by its norm.Two vectors x 1 and x 2 are called l<strong>in</strong>early <strong>in</strong>dependent if the follow<strong>in</strong>grelation holds only for the case when both c 1 and c 2 are equal to zero:c 1 x 1 c 2 x 2 0If this relation holds for some nonzero values of c 1 and c 2 , then the vectorsare said to be l<strong>in</strong>early dependent.Transpose of a MatrixThe transpose of a matrix A, denoted A T , is a matrix that has the first rowof A as its first column, the second row of A as its second column, and so on.In other words, the (i, j)th element of the A matrix is the (j, i)th element ofthe matrix A T . It follows immediately from this def<strong>in</strong>ition that for symmetricmatrices, A A T .Inverse of a MatrixFor any given n n matrix A, if the n n matrix B is such that the productof the two matrices gives rise to a matrix that has all diagonal elementsequal to one and the rest zero, then the matrix B is said to be the <strong>in</strong>verseof the matrix A. The matrix with diagonal elements equal to one and alloff-diagonal elements zero is referred to as the identity matrix and is


Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 15denoted I. The <strong>in</strong>verse of the matrix A is denoted A 1 . A necessary conditionfor a matrix to be <strong>in</strong>vertible is that all its column vectors are l<strong>in</strong>early<strong>in</strong>dependent.In the special case where the transpose of a matrix is equal to the<strong>in</strong>verse of a matrix, that is, A T A 1 , the matrix is referred to as anorthogonal matrix.Eigenvalues and EigenvectorsThe eigenvalues of a square matrix A are real or complex numbers suchthat the vector equation Ax x has nontrivial solutions. The correspond<strong>in</strong>gvectors x0 are referred to as the eigenvectors of A. Any n nmatrix has n eigenvalues, and associated with each eigenvalue is a correspond<strong>in</strong>geigenvector. It is possible that for some matrices not all eigenvaluesand eigenvectors are dist<strong>in</strong>ct. The sum of the n eigenvalues equals thesum of the entries on the diagonal of the matrix A, called the trace of A.Thus,trace A ani1a ii anl ii1If 0 is an eigenvalue of the matrix, the matrix is referred to as a s<strong>in</strong>gularmatrix. Matrices that are s<strong>in</strong>gular do not have an <strong>in</strong>verse.Diagonalization of a MatrixWhen x is an eigenvector of the matrix A, the product Ax is equivalent tothe multiplication of the vector x by a scalar quantity. This scalar quantityhappens to be the eigenvalue of the matrix. One can conjecture from thisthat a matrix can be turned <strong>in</strong>to a diagonal matrix by us<strong>in</strong>g eigenvectorsappropriately. In particular, if the columns of matrix M are formed us<strong>in</strong>gthe eigenvectors of A, then the matrix operation M 1 AM is a diagonalmatrix with eigenvalues of A as the diagonal elements. However, for this tobe true, the matrix M must be <strong>in</strong>vertible. Stated differently, the eigenvectorsof the matrix A must form a set of l<strong>in</strong>early <strong>in</strong>dependent vectors.It is useful to remark here that any matrix operation of the type B 1 ABwhere B is an <strong>in</strong>vertible matrix is referred to as a similarity transformation.Under a similarity transformation, eigenvalues rema<strong>in</strong> unchanged.Properties of Symmetric MatricesSymmetric matrices have the property that all eigenvalues are real numbers.If, <strong>in</strong> addition, the eigenvalues are all positive, then the matrix is referred to


16 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSas a positive-def<strong>in</strong>ite matrix. An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g property of symmetric matrices isthat they are always diagonalizable. Furthermore, the matrix M constructedus<strong>in</strong>g the normalized eigenvectors of a symmetric matrix is orthogonal.A well-known example of a symmetric matrix is the covariancematrix of security returns. For an n-asset portfolio, if the random vectorof security returns is denoted by r and the mean of the random vectorby , then the n n matrix given by E[(r )(r ) T ] is termed thecovariance matrix of security returns. Although covariance matrices arepositive def<strong>in</strong>ite by def<strong>in</strong>ition (assum<strong>in</strong>g the n assets are dist<strong>in</strong>ct), covariancematrices estimated us<strong>in</strong>g historical data can sometimes turn out tobe s<strong>in</strong>gular.Cholesky DecompositionThe Cholesky decomposition is concerned with the factorization of a symmetricand positive-def<strong>in</strong>ite matrix <strong>in</strong>to the product of a lower and anupper triangular matrix. A matrix is said to be lower triangular if all itselements above the diagonal are zero. Similarly, an upper triangular matrixis one with all elements below the diagonal zero. If the matrix is symmetricand positive def<strong>in</strong>ite, the upper triangular matrix is equal to the transposeof the lower triangular matrix. Specifically, if the lower triangularmatrix is denoted by L, then the positive-def<strong>in</strong>ite matrix can be writtenas LL T . Such a factorization of the matrix is called the Choleskydecomposition.The Cholesky factorization of a matrix f<strong>in</strong>ds application <strong>in</strong> simulat<strong>in</strong>grandom vectors from a multivariate distribution. Specifically, if one has togenerate a sequence of normally distributed random vectors hav<strong>in</strong>g an n ncovariance matrix , the Cholesky decomposition helps achieve this <strong>in</strong> twosimple steps. In the first step, one generates a random vector x compris<strong>in</strong>gn uncorrelated standardized normal random variables. In the second step,one constructs the random vector z Lx, which has the desired covariancematrix. To see why this is true, first note that z is a zero-mean random vectorbecause x is a zero-mean random vector. In this case, the covariancematrix of the random vector z can be written asE(z z T ) E(L x x T L T ) LE(x x T )L TBecause the random vector x comprises uncorrelated normal random variables,the covariance matrix given by E(x x T ) is equal to the identity matrix.From this it follows thatE(z z T ) LL T ©


Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 17The elements of the matrix L that represents the Cholesky decompositionof the matrix can be computed us<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g rule:i1l ii a s ii B a lik 2 b ,l ji 1 i1a sl ji a l jk l ik b ,iik1k1i 1, 2, ... , nj i 1, ... , nI mentioned that covariance matrices estimated from historical data couldbe s<strong>in</strong>gular. If this happens, we artificially add some variance to each of therandom variables so that the covariance matrix is positive def<strong>in</strong>ite. For<strong>in</strong>stance, if E denotes a diagonal matrix with small positive elements, thenthe matrix E has the property that it is positive def<strong>in</strong>ite and theCholesky decomposition can be computed.Markov MatrixA real n n matrix P [p ij ] is called a Markov matrix if its elements havethe follow<strong>in</strong>g properties:na p ij 1, i 1,2, ... ,nj1p ij 0, i, j 1,2, ... ,nThis def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>in</strong>dicates that the elements <strong>in</strong> each row of a Markov matrixare non-negative and sum to one. As a result, any row vector hav<strong>in</strong>g thisproperty can be considered to represent a valid probability mass function.This leads to the <strong>in</strong>terpretation of any vector hav<strong>in</strong>g this property as aprobability vector.Markov matrices have some <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g properties. The matrix formedby tak<strong>in</strong>g the product of two Markov matrices is also a Markov matrix. Ifone multiplies a probability vector by a Markov matrix, the result is anotherprobability vector. Markov matrices f<strong>in</strong>d applications <strong>in</strong> many differentfields. In f<strong>in</strong>ance, Markov matrices are used to model the rat<strong>in</strong>g migrationsof obligors. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a 1-year rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix is simply a probabilisticrepresentation of the possible credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs an obligor could have<strong>in</strong> 1 year. The probability of migrat<strong>in</strong>g to another rat<strong>in</strong>g grade is a functionof the current credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the obligor.


18 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSFor purpose of illustration, consider the follow<strong>in</strong>g Markov matrix:0.6 0.3 0.1P £ 0.1 0.7 0.2 §0 0 1This Markov matrix has three states, which can be thought of as represent<strong>in</strong>gan <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade rat<strong>in</strong>g, a non-<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade rat<strong>in</strong>g, and adefault state for the obligor, respectively. The first row represents the rat<strong>in</strong>gmigration probabilities for an obligor rated <strong>in</strong>vestment grade. If these probabilitiesrepresent 1-year migration probabilities, one can <strong>in</strong>terpret from thefirst row of the matrix that there is a 0.1 probability that the <strong>in</strong>vestmentgradeobligor will default <strong>in</strong> 1 year from now. However, if one wants toknow the probability that an <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade obligor will default <strong>in</strong> 2years from now, one can compute this as follows:0.6 0.3 0.1 0.6 0.3 0.1[1 0 0] £ 0.1 0.7 0.2 §£ 0.1 0.7 0.2 § [0.39 0.39 0.22]0 0 1 0 0 1In this computation, the probability vector [1 0 0] denotes that the obligorhas an <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade rat<strong>in</strong>g to start with. Multiply<strong>in</strong>g this probability vectorby P gives the probability vector 1 year from now. If one multiplies thisprobability vector once more by P, one gets the probabilities of occupy<strong>in</strong>g differentstates 2 years from now. Actual computations carried out <strong>in</strong>dicate thatthe probability that an <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade obligor will default <strong>in</strong> 2 years is 0.22.In practice, rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies estimate multiyear rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrices<strong>in</strong> addition to the standard 1-year rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix. A question ofgreater <strong>in</strong>terest is whether one can derive a rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix for a6-month or a 3-month horizon us<strong>in</strong>g the 1-year rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix. Theshort answer to this question is yes, and the way to do this is to perform aneigenvector decomposition of the 1-year rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix. If Mdenotes the matrix of eigenvectors of the 1-year rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix Pand is a diagonal matrix whose diagonal elements are the eigenvalues of P,then one knows from the earlier result on the diagonalization of a matrix thatthe operation M 1 PM gives the diagonal matrix . From this it follows thatP MM 1The 3-month rat<strong>in</strong>g migration matrix, for <strong>in</strong>stance, can now be computedas follows:P 1/4 M 1/4 M 1


Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 19The matrix P 1/4 computed by perform<strong>in</strong>g this operation is a valid Markovmatrix provided P represents a Markov matrix. Comput<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g transitionmatrices for horizons less than 1 year us<strong>in</strong>g the forego<strong>in</strong>g matrixdecomposition makes use of the result that the matrices P and P 1/n share thesame eigenvectors. By perform<strong>in</strong>g the forego<strong>in</strong>g operations on the 3 3matrix P, one can derive the follow<strong>in</strong>g 3-month rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix:It is easy to verify that this matrix is a Markov matrix.Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal Component Analysis0.8736 0.1055 0.0209P 1/4 £ 0.0351 0.9088 0.0561 §0 0 1Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysis is concerned with expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g thevariance–covariance structure of n random variables through a few l<strong>in</strong>earcomb<strong>in</strong>ations of the orig<strong>in</strong>al variables. Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysis oftenreveals relationships that are sometimes not obvious, and the analysis isbased on historical data. Our <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysis lies<strong>in</strong> its application to the empirical model<strong>in</strong>g of the yield curve dynamics. Forthe purpose of illustrat<strong>in</strong>g the mathematical concepts beh<strong>in</strong>d pr<strong>in</strong>cipal componentanalysis, consider the n random variables of <strong>in</strong>terest to be the weeklyyield changes for different maturities along the yield curve. Denote theserandom variables by y 1 , y 2 , ... , y n .An algebraic <strong>in</strong>terpretation of pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysis is that pr<strong>in</strong>cipalcomponents are particular l<strong>in</strong>ear comb<strong>in</strong>ations of the n random variables.The geometric <strong>in</strong>terpretation is that these l<strong>in</strong>ear comb<strong>in</strong>ations representthe selection of a new coord<strong>in</strong>ate system. Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components depend solelyon the covariance matrix of the n random variables and do not require themultivariate normal distribution assumption for the random variables.Denote the n random variables by the vector Y [y 1 , y 2 , ... , y n ] T andthe eigenvalues of the n n covariance matrix by 1 2 n 0.By def<strong>in</strong>ition, E[(Y )(Y ) T ], where is the mean of vector Y .Now consider the follow<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>ear comb<strong>in</strong>ations of Y :x 1 / 1 T Y / 11 y 1 / 12 y 2 / 1n y nx 2 / 2 T Y / 21 y 1 / 22 y 2 / 2n y nx n / n T Y / n1 y 1 / n2 y 2 / nn y nIn these equations, i are unit vectors and x 1 , x 2 , ... , x n represent new randomvariables. The vector i is usually <strong>in</strong>terpreted as a direction vector,


20 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSwhich changes the coord<strong>in</strong>ate axes of the orig<strong>in</strong>al random variables. It iseasy to verify that the variance of the random variable x i is given byvar(x i ) varA/ Ti Y B / Ti ©/ iThe covariance of the random variables x i and x k is given bycov(x i , x k ) E[A/ Ti Y / Ti BA/ Tk Y / Tk B T ] / Ti E[AY BAY B T ]/ k / Ti ©/ kTo compute the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components, one first needs to def<strong>in</strong>e what pr<strong>in</strong>cipalcomponents are. A simple def<strong>in</strong>ition of pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components is thatthey are uncorrelated l<strong>in</strong>ear comb<strong>in</strong>ations of the orig<strong>in</strong>al random variablessuch that the variances expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the newly constructed random variablesare as large as possible.So far, I have not mentioned how to choose the direction vectors toachieve this. In fact, it is quite simple. All one needs to do is to choose thedirection vectors to be the normalized eigenvectors of the covariance matrix. If one does this, the l<strong>in</strong>ear transformations give rise to random variablesthat represent the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components of the covariance matrix. To seewhy this is the case, note that when the vector i is an eigenvector of thematrix , then i gives i i . From this it follows thatvar(x i ) / Ti ©/ i l i / Ti / i l iIn other words, the variances of the new random variables are equal to theeigenvalues of the covariance matrix. Furthermore, by construction, therandom variables are uncorrelated because the covariance between any tworandom variables x i and x k is zero when i k. The random variable x 1 isthe first pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component and its variance, given by 1 , is greater thanthe variance of any other random variables one can construct. The secondpr<strong>in</strong>cipal component is x 2 , whose variance is equal to 2 .The sum of the variances of the new random variables constructed isequal to the sum of the eigenvalues of the covariance matrix. The sum ofthe variances of the orig<strong>in</strong>al random variables is equal to the sum of thediagonal entries of the covariance matrix , which by def<strong>in</strong>ition is equal tothe trace of the matrix. Because the trace of a matrix is equal to the sum ofthe eigenvalues of the matrix, one gets the follow<strong>in</strong>g identity:nna var(y i ) a var(x i )i1i1


Mathematical Prelim<strong>in</strong>aries 21It immediately follows from this relation that the proportion of variance ofthe orig<strong>in</strong>al random variables expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the ith pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component isgiven byl il 1 l 2 l nThe pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components derived by perform<strong>in</strong>g an eigenvector decompositionof the covariance matrix are optimal <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the variance structureover some historical time period. Outside this sample period overwhich the covariance matrix is estimated, the eigenvectors may not be optimaldirection vectors <strong>in</strong> the sense of maximiz<strong>in</strong>g the observed varianceus<strong>in</strong>g a few pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components. Moreover, the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal componentdirection vectors keep chang<strong>in</strong>g as new data come <strong>in</strong>, and giv<strong>in</strong>g a risk<strong>in</strong>terpretation to these vectors becomes difficult. Given these difficulties,one might like to know whether one could choose some other direction vectorsthat lend themselves to easy <strong>in</strong>terpretation, but nonetheless expla<strong>in</strong> asignificant amount of variance <strong>in</strong> the orig<strong>in</strong>al data us<strong>in</strong>g only a few components.The answer is yes, with the only requirement that the directionvectors be chosen to be l<strong>in</strong>early <strong>in</strong>dependent.If, for <strong>in</strong>stance, one chooses two direction vectors s and t, denotedshift and twist vectors, respectively, then the variance of the new randomvariables iss 2 s / Ts ©/ ss 2 t / Tt ©/ tThe proportion of variance <strong>in</strong> the orig<strong>in</strong>al data expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the twodepends on how much correlation there is between the two random variablesconstructed. The correlation between the random variables is given byr cov(/ s, / t)s s s t / Ts ©/ ts s s tThe proportion of total variance expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the two random variables iss 2 s (1 r)s 2 tl 1 l 2 l nQUESTIONS1. A die is rolled 10 times. F<strong>in</strong>d the probability that the face 6 will show(a) at least two times and (b) exactly two times.


22 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS2. The number that shows up when a die is rolled is a random variable.Compute the mean and the variance of this random variable.3. A normally distributed random variable has 0.5 and 1.2.Compute the 10th percentile of the distribution.4. A beta distribution with parameters 1.4 and 1.58 is used tosimulate the recovery values from defaulted bonds. Compute the probabilitythat the recovery value dur<strong>in</strong>g the simulations lies <strong>in</strong> the range20 to 80 percent of the par value of the bond. What are the mean andthe volatility of the recovery rate process simulated?5. If a uniform distribution is used to restrict the simulated recovery ratesto lie <strong>in</strong> the range 20 to 80 percent of the par value of the bond, whatare the mean and the volatility of the recovery rate process?6. Show that if A and B are any two n n Markov matrices, then theproduct of the two matrices is also a Markov matrix.7. For any Markov matrix P, show that P n and P 1/n are also Markovmatrices for any <strong>in</strong>teger n.8. I computed the 3-month rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix P 1/4 <strong>in</strong> the numericalexample under Markov matrices. Compute the 1-month and 6-monthrat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrices for this example.9. Compute the eigenvalues, eigenvectors, and Cholesky decomposition ofthe follow<strong>in</strong>g matrix:A £1 2 02 5 0§0 0 210. Compute the proportion of total variance expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the first twopr<strong>in</strong>cipal components for the matrix A <strong>in</strong> Question 9.11. If the direction vectors are chosen to be [1 0 1] T and [1 0 0] T<strong>in</strong>stead of the first two eigenvectors of the matrix A <strong>in</strong> Question 9,compute the total variance expla<strong>in</strong>ed by these two direction vectors.


CHAPTER 3The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> MarketIn this chapter, I describe the features of corporate bonds and identify therisks associated with <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> corporate bonds. I then discuss thepractical difficulties related to the trad<strong>in</strong>g of corporate bonds as opposed togovernment bonds aris<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>in</strong>creased transaction costs and lack oftransparent pric<strong>in</strong>g sources. I highlight the important role played by corporatebonds <strong>in</strong> buffer<strong>in</strong>g the impact of f<strong>in</strong>ancial crises and exam<strong>in</strong>e the relativemarket size and historical performance of corporate bonds. F<strong>in</strong>ally, Iprovide some justification as to why the corporate bond market is an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>gasset class for the reserves portfolio of central banks and for pensionfunds.FEATURES OF CORPORATE BONDS<strong>Corporate</strong> bonds are debt obligations issued by private and public corporationsto raise capital to f<strong>in</strong>ance their bus<strong>in</strong>ess operations. The major corporatebond issuers can be classified under the follow<strong>in</strong>g categories: (1)public utilities, (2) transportation companies, (3) <strong>in</strong>dustrial corporations,(4) f<strong>in</strong>ancial services companies, and (5) conglomerates. <strong>Corporate</strong> bondsdenom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> U.S. dollars are typically issued <strong>in</strong> multiples of $1,000 andare traded primarily <strong>in</strong> the over-the-counter (OTC) market.Unlike owners of stocks, holders of corporate bonds do not have ownershiprights <strong>in</strong> the corporation issu<strong>in</strong>g the bonds. <strong>Bond</strong>holders, however,have priority on legal claims over common and preferred stockholders onboth <strong>in</strong>come and assets of the corporation for the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal and <strong>in</strong>terest dueto them. The promises of corporate bond issuers and the rights of <strong>in</strong>vestorswho buy them are set forth <strong>in</strong> contracts termed <strong>in</strong>dentures. The <strong>in</strong>denture,which is pr<strong>in</strong>ted on the bond certificate, conta<strong>in</strong>s the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation:the duties and obligations of the trustee, all the rights of the bondholder,how and when the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal will be repaid, the rate of <strong>in</strong>terest, the descriptionof any property to be pledged as collateral, and the steps the bondholdercan take <strong>in</strong> the event of default.23


24 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS<strong>Corporate</strong> bonds are issued <strong>in</strong> the form of registered bonds or bookentrybonds. Registered bonds refer to those corporate bonds that areissued as certificates with the owner’s name pr<strong>in</strong>ted on them. There are nocoupons attached for the owner to submit for payment of <strong>in</strong>terest. Theissuer’s trustee sends the <strong>in</strong>terest to the bondholder at the appropriate <strong>in</strong>tervalsand forwards the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal at maturity. Book-entry bonds are thosethat are issued without certificates. Book-entry bonds have largely replacedregistered bonds as the prevail<strong>in</strong>g form of issuance. With book-entry securities,a bond issue has only one master certificate, which is usually kept ata securities depository. The ownership of book-entry bonds is recorded <strong>in</strong>the <strong>in</strong>vestor’s brokerage account and <strong>in</strong>terest and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments areforwarded to this account.<strong>Corporate</strong> bonds are broadly classified <strong>in</strong>to <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade and non<strong>in</strong>vestment-gradebonds. Investment-grade bonds are those that have a creditrat<strong>in</strong>g of BBB-m<strong>in</strong>us or higher as rated by Standard & Poor’s or, equivalently,a credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of Baa3 or higher as rated by Moody’s. Companies thatissue such bonds are assumed to have a reasonably good credit stand<strong>in</strong>g.<strong>Bond</strong>s that have a rat<strong>in</strong>g below this are referred to as non-<strong>in</strong>vestment-gradeor high-yield bonds. Such bonds are issued by newer or start-up companiesor companies that have had f<strong>in</strong>ancial problems. The credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of thebond issuer provides bondholders with a simple system to measure the abilityof the issuer to honor its f<strong>in</strong>ancial obligations.<strong>Bond</strong> CollateralizationFrom the <strong>in</strong>vestor’s perspective, corporate bonds offer an attractive yield pickupover comparable-maturity government bonds. However, whether the currentyields will be realized over the <strong>in</strong>vestment horizon of <strong>in</strong>terest depends onthe ability of the issuer to honor the promised payments, which <strong>in</strong> turn is determ<strong>in</strong>edby the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the bond issuer. Generally, the lower the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g,the higher the yield pickup. An equally important factor that determ<strong>in</strong>esthe yield differential versus the government bond is the collateral attached tothe bond issue. <strong>Bond</strong>s that have collateral attached to them are called securedbonds and those with no collateral are called unsecured bonds. For identicalbond maturities, secured bonds of any issuer have a lower yield relative to unsecuredbonds of the same issuer. Depend<strong>in</strong>g on the nature of the collateral or itsabsence, corporate bonds can be further classified <strong>in</strong>to debenture bonds, mortgagebonds, collateral trust bonds, or equipment trust certificates.Debenture <strong>Bond</strong>s Most corporate bonds are debentures, which means theyare senior unsecured debt obligations backed only by the issuer’s generalcredit and the capacity of its cash flow to repay <strong>in</strong>terest and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal.Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g this, senior unsecured bonds generally have the protection


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 25of a negative pledge provision. This provision requires the issuer to providesecurity for the unsecured bonds <strong>in</strong> the event that it subsequently pledges itsassets to secure other debt obligations. The <strong>in</strong>tention is to prevent othercreditors from obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a senior position at the expense of exist<strong>in</strong>g creditors.However, it is not <strong>in</strong>tended to prevent other creditors from shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>the position of debenture holders.Another k<strong>in</strong>d of debenture bond, which has lower priority on claims tosenior unsecured bonds, is a subord<strong>in</strong>ated bond. In exchange for this lowerpriority on claims <strong>in</strong> the event of bankruptcy, the yield on subord<strong>in</strong>atedbonds is higher than on senior unsecured bonds.Mortgage <strong>Bond</strong>s <strong>Bond</strong>s that have real estate or other physical assets pledgedaga<strong>in</strong>st them are referred to as mortgage bonds. The real assets pledgedmust have a market value greater than the bond issue size. Among corporates,the largest issuers of mortgage bonds are electric utility companies.Other utilities, such as telephone companies and gas pipel<strong>in</strong>e and distributionfirms, also use mortgage bonds to a limited extent as a source of f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g.In the event of default on coupon or pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payment by the issuer,the pledged assets are sold off to repay the mortgage bondholders.There are various k<strong>in</strong>ds of mortgage bonds, such as first, prior, junior,second, and so on. This classification reflects the priority of the lien or legalclaim the bondholder has aga<strong>in</strong>st the specified pledged property. When<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> mortgage bonds, it is important to check how much of the othermortgage debt of the issuer is secured by the same collateral and whetherthe lien support<strong>in</strong>g the other mortgage debt has greater or lower prioritythan the issue that is be<strong>in</strong>g bought.Another categorization of mortgage debt is <strong>in</strong> terms of open-ended andclosed-end mortgage bonds. If the mortgage bonds are pledged with closedendassets, these assets can only be sold to repay the <strong>in</strong>terest and pr<strong>in</strong>cipaldue for the particular issue <strong>in</strong> the event of default. On the other hand, if themortgage bonds are pledged with open-ended assets, these assets may alsobe pledged aga<strong>in</strong>st other open-ended issues.Collateral Trust <strong>Bond</strong>s Collateral trust bonds are those that are secured byf<strong>in</strong>ancial assets such as stocks, receivables, bonds, and securities other thanreal property. A trustee holds the eligible collateral and the collateral valuemust be at least equal to the value of the bonds. To ensure this is the case,the trustee periodically marks to market the collateral to ensure that the liquidationvalue is <strong>in</strong> excess of the amount needed to repay the entire outstand<strong>in</strong>gbonds l<strong>in</strong>ked to it and the accrued <strong>in</strong>terest. If this condition is notmet, the issuer is required to br<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> additional collateral, fail<strong>in</strong>g which, thetrustee sells the collateral and redeems the bonds. Collateral trust bonds aretypically issued by vehicle-leas<strong>in</strong>g firms.


26 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEquipment Trust Certificates An equipment trust certificate is a bond that iscollateralized by ownership of specific equipment, often capital <strong>in</strong> nature.Railroads and airl<strong>in</strong>es issue this type of bond as a way to pay for new equipmentat relatively low <strong>in</strong>terest rates. Essentially this <strong>in</strong>volves transferr<strong>in</strong>gthe ownership of the asset, such as an aircraft or a locomotive, to a trustee,who then issues certificates <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the beneficial ownership of the asset.Such equipment trust certificates are issued at 80 percent of the value of theequipment; the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g 20 percent is paid by the railroad or airl<strong>in</strong>e seek<strong>in</strong>gthe f<strong>in</strong>ance. Due to the collateral value of the equipment trust certificatesand superior stand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy proceed<strong>in</strong>gs, rat<strong>in</strong>gs for equipmenttrust certificates are usually higher than on other debt securities issuedby the same corporation.Remarks In general, bonds that are backed by some form of collateral areclassified under securitized assets. If the collateral consists of receivablesother than a mortgage loan, such as credit card receivables, auto loans,manufactured-hous<strong>in</strong>g contracts, and home-equity loans, then the collateralizedbond is referred to as an asset-backed security (ABS). <strong>Bond</strong>s backedby first mortgages, although the most common securitized asset, are usuallyconsidered to be a separate <strong>in</strong>vestment category and are referred to as mortgage-backedsecurities (MBS). The analysis presented <strong>in</strong> this book is notapplicable to mortgage-backed securities.Although <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple the management of an ABS portfolio can be analyzedus<strong>in</strong>g the framework presented <strong>in</strong> this book, some features of ABSssuch as <strong>in</strong>ternal and external forms of credit enhancement and whether theassets are amortiz<strong>in</strong>g require careful exam<strong>in</strong>ation. Moreover, the loan orig<strong>in</strong>atorsof such securities, commonly referred to as the issuers of ABSs, are<strong>in</strong> fact the sponsors and not the issuers of these securities. This is achievedby the sponsor sell<strong>in</strong>g the assets to a special-purpose vehicle (SPV), thestructural feature of which is to provide bankruptcy remoteness betweenthe trust that issues the bonds and the loan sponsor who orig<strong>in</strong>ates them.These factors tend to complicate the credit risk analysis of an ABS portfolio.Hence, the focus <strong>in</strong> this book is primarily on the portfolio managementof unsecuritized corporate bonds.Investment <strong>Risk</strong>sAn <strong>in</strong>vestor who buys corporate bonds is exposed to a variety of risks. Thechief among them are market risk, credit risk, liquidity risk, and economicrisk.Market <strong>Risk</strong> Prices of corporate bonds are sensitive to changes <strong>in</strong> the levelof <strong>in</strong>terest rates. Ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest rates cause the prices of bonds to fall; the


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 27longer the maturity of the bond, the greater is the price depriciation. Thisrisk, generally referred to as <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk, is common to any fixed<strong>in</strong>comesecurity. Another source of market risk can arise from early redemptionsif the bond has a call provision. In this case, the issuer has the right toredeem the debt, fully or partially, before the scheduled maturity date of thebond. Call provisions limit the potential price appreciation when <strong>in</strong>terestrates fall. Because the call provision puts the <strong>in</strong>vestor at a disadvantage,callable bonds carry higher yields than noncallable bonds. The relative percentageof unsecuritized corporate bonds with embedded options is, however,quite small. As of end of 2002, callable/puttable corporate bonds constituted10.1 percent of the number of issues and 5.7 percent of marketcapitalization of the Lehman Brothers corporate bond <strong>in</strong>dex.<strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> A major source of risk fac<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> the corporate bondmarket is whether the bond issuer has the f<strong>in</strong>ancial capacity to meet thecontractual coupon and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments. This risk is usually referred toas default risk, and it <strong>in</strong>creases as the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the issuer decl<strong>in</strong>es.Apart from default risk, corporate bonds are also exposed to price changesthat result from perceived changes <strong>in</strong> the ability of the issuer to meet thepromised cash flows. This form of risk is usually referred to as downgraderisk. Default risk and downgrade risk are collectively called credit risk, andthey constitute a major component of risk fac<strong>in</strong>g corporate bond <strong>in</strong>vestors.Liquidity <strong>Risk</strong> The risk stemm<strong>in</strong>g from the lack of marketability of an <strong>in</strong>strumentis referred to as liquidity risk. <strong>Bond</strong>s, such as U.S. Treasuries, thattrade frequently and <strong>in</strong> large amounts have less liquidity risk than corporatebonds. An <strong>in</strong>dicative measure of liquidity risk is the difference betweenthe bid price and ask price of a security and the size that can be transactedat this bid price. The greater the bid–ask spread and/or the smaller the bidsize, the greater the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is surround<strong>in</strong>g the true market value of thesecurity. As the <strong>in</strong>vestor’s hold<strong>in</strong>g period of the corporate bond <strong>in</strong>creases,liquidity risk becomes only a small fraction of the overall risk fac<strong>in</strong>g a corporatebond <strong>in</strong>vestor. However, one has to bear <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d that when an<strong>in</strong>vestor tries to sell a corporate bond due to deteriorat<strong>in</strong>g credit conditionsof the issuer, the liquidity risk fac<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>vestor is greatest.Economic <strong>Risk</strong> Economic risk refers to the vulnerability of the corporatebond’s return to downturns <strong>in</strong> the economy. Unlike credit risk, which is specificto a particular issuer, economic risk affects the returns of all corporatebonds. This is because earn<strong>in</strong>gs capabilities of most companies are tied tothe state of the economy. Dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of economic contraction, companyearn<strong>in</strong>gs are reduced, which <strong>in</strong> turn reduces their capacity to meet paymentobligations on outstand<strong>in</strong>g debt. As a consequence, the general level


28 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSof credit spreads relative to government debt <strong>in</strong>creases across the entirespectrum of corporate bonds due to a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the ability of many corporationsto service debt obligations. This results <strong>in</strong> a loss <strong>in</strong> market value ofthe corporate bond portfolio due to widen<strong>in</strong>g credit spreads for corporateborrowers across the entire spectrum.CORPORATE BOND TRADINGThe over-the-counter nature of the corporate bond market leads to a privatelynegotiated secondary market where bonds tend to turn over <strong>in</strong>frequently.As a result, the corporate bond market suffers from the lack oftransparency and availability of a central pric<strong>in</strong>g mechanism. Indeed, pricetransparency is essential to build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestor confidence, which <strong>in</strong> turn canresult <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>crease of trad<strong>in</strong>g volume. In fact, the trad<strong>in</strong>g volume <strong>in</strong> thecorporate bond market is less than 1 percent of outstand<strong>in</strong>g market capitalization,whereas <strong>in</strong> the case of the U.S. Treasury bond market, trad<strong>in</strong>gvolume is close to 10 percent of the Treasury bond market capitalization.In this section, I discuss some practical issues connected with corporatebond trad<strong>in</strong>g namely, the trad<strong>in</strong>g costs <strong>in</strong>volved, the impact on portfoliomanagement styles, and pric<strong>in</strong>g anomalies of corporate bonds.Trad<strong>in</strong>g CostsI have already mentioned that the turnover <strong>in</strong> the corporate bond market ismuch lower than the turnover <strong>in</strong> the government bond market. The ma<strong>in</strong>reason for the lower turnover is the wider bid–ask spreads that are quotedfor corporate bonds. Wider bid–ask spreads lead to high transaction costsif corporate bonds are frequently turned over. To m<strong>in</strong>imize the transactioncosts, most <strong>in</strong>vestors try to follow a buy-and-hold strategy when <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> corporate bonds. Such a strategy has the detrimental effect of further<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g bid–ask spreads on bonds that are not recent issues. <strong>Corporate</strong>bonds denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> U.S. dollars are usually quoted <strong>in</strong> terms of yieldspread over comparable-maturity U.S. Treasuries. 1 Typical bid–ask spreadson such quotes can vary from 5 to as much as 10 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts, which isroughly 10 times greater than the bid–ask yield spreads observed on U.S.Treasuries.The wider bid–ask spreads and smaller bid sizes for corporate bondstend to make this asset class lack the traditional liquidity enjoyed by governmentbonds. In broad terms, a liquid f<strong>in</strong>ancial asset is one for whichlarge numbers of buyers and sellers are present so that <strong>in</strong>com<strong>in</strong>g orders canbe matched without affect<strong>in</strong>g the market price of the asset. Although corporatebonds are less liquid than government bonds, it is important to note


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 29that illiquidity is not a static attribute of corporate bonds. On the contrary,significant fluctuations <strong>in</strong> the liquidity of corporate bonds can often occur<strong>in</strong> response to changes <strong>in</strong> macroeconomic trends or perceived risks of particularcorporate sectors. The corporate bond market has a history of alternat<strong>in</strong>gbetween periods of confidence and transparency marked by multipledealer quotes and tight bid–ask spreads and periods of gloom and uncerta<strong>in</strong>tycharacterized by low trad<strong>in</strong>g volumes and wide bid–ask spreads.To understand why trad<strong>in</strong>g costs are high for corporate bonds, it isimportant to exam<strong>in</strong>e the mechanics of corporate bond trad<strong>in</strong>g. As previouslystated, corporate bonds are primarily traded <strong>in</strong> the secondary market.The secondary market trad<strong>in</strong>g is done through bond dealers <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestmentbanks rather than through exchanges or on electronic platforms. <strong>Bond</strong> dealersserve as <strong>in</strong>termediaries between <strong>in</strong>vestors want<strong>in</strong>g to buy and sell corporatebonds. Because <strong>in</strong>vestors turn over corporate bonds less frequently,match<strong>in</strong>g the buy and sell orders for dealers can take sometimes severaldays, and <strong>in</strong> the worst case, even several weeks. Dur<strong>in</strong>g this period, thedealer is forced to hold an <strong>in</strong>ventory of the bond, which needs to bef<strong>in</strong>anced until a seller can be found. While the corporate bond is held <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ventory, the dealer faces the risk that the price of the bond can fall due toeither a negative earn<strong>in</strong>g surprise announcement or an actual downgrade ofthe corporation that issued the bond. Moreover, the <strong>in</strong>ventory cost <strong>in</strong>creasesover time because risk managers penalize stale <strong>in</strong>ventories with higher capitalcharges. To compensate for these risks, corporate bond dealers usuallycharge wider bid–ask spreads to cushion their potential losses.Hav<strong>in</strong>g exam<strong>in</strong>ed why trad<strong>in</strong>g costs for corporate bonds are high, Iturn to the follow<strong>in</strong>g practical questions: How much does it cost to trade acorporate bond, and do the trad<strong>in</strong>g costs differ for different bond maturities?The trad<strong>in</strong>g cost of any bond is a function of the quoted bid–ask yieldspread and the duration of the bond. Specifically, if D denotes the modifiedduration of the bond and s the bid–ask yield spread, then the trad<strong>in</strong>g costfor the bond is given by 2Trad<strong>in</strong>g cost D sThis formula suggests that trad<strong>in</strong>g costs for a corporate bond with longermaturity are greater. If, for <strong>in</strong>stance, the bid–ask yield spread is 5 basispo<strong>in</strong>ts and the modified duration of the bond is 4 years, then the trad<strong>in</strong>gcost is 20 cents for a $100 face value of the bond. In a portfolio context,the trad<strong>in</strong>g cost is measured <strong>in</strong> terms of the annual turnover of the portfolio.3 Assum<strong>in</strong>g that the average duration of the portfolio is 4 years and theportfolio turnover is 100 percent dur<strong>in</strong>g the year, the annual trad<strong>in</strong>g costsfor the portfolio is roughly 20 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts if the bid–ask yield spread is 5basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. This trad<strong>in</strong>g cost is quite high relative to the trad<strong>in</strong>g costs


30 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS<strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g a government bond portfolio. As a numerical comparison,trad<strong>in</strong>g costs for a government bond portfolio hav<strong>in</strong>g the sameduration and turnover ratio are about 3 to 4 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts.Portfolio Management StyleThe higher trad<strong>in</strong>g costs for corporate bond portfolios <strong>in</strong>fluence portfoliomanagement styles that are pursued to add value aga<strong>in</strong>st a given benchmark.Consider<strong>in</strong>g that average portfolio trad<strong>in</strong>g costs are fairly determ<strong>in</strong>istic,corporate portfolio managers try to m<strong>in</strong>imize this consciously by limit<strong>in</strong>gthe portfolio turnover. Typical annual turnover ratios for activelymanaged corporate bond portfolios are about 75 percent, whereas for governmentbond portfolios ratios can be <strong>in</strong> the region of 150 percent. As aresult, the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> trad<strong>in</strong>g costs to manage a corporate bond portfolio isroughly <strong>in</strong> the region of 10 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts per annum more than that <strong>in</strong>curredto manage a government bond portfolio. When later I explore alternativeasset allocation strategies to improve the <strong>in</strong>vestment returns on assets undermanagement, I will take <strong>in</strong>to account this additional trad<strong>in</strong>g cost for a corporatebond portfolio.As a consequence of the higher transaction costs <strong>in</strong>curred for manag<strong>in</strong>gcorporate bonds, portfolio management styles of corporate and governmentbond portfolio managers differ. In particular, <strong>in</strong>vestment strategies of corporatebond portfolio managers tend to focus on analyz<strong>in</strong>g the long-termfundamentals of bond issuers so that a buy-and-hold strategy can be pursuedwhile seek<strong>in</strong>g to outperform a given benchmark. Portfolio managers <strong>in</strong>charge of manag<strong>in</strong>g government bond portfolios, on the other hand, tendto pursue yield-curve strategies to add value aga<strong>in</strong>st their benchmarks. Inaddition, government bond portfolio managers may be able to repo outbonds that go on specials, and this could generate some additional <strong>in</strong>come.With respect to manag<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond portfolio, I identified transactioncosts as an important factor that <strong>in</strong>fluences the trad<strong>in</strong>g styles of portfoliomanagers. I now highlight some practical difficulties <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>ga corporate bond portfolio as opposed to a government bondportfolio. Much of the practical difficulties stem from the smaller issue sizeof corporate bonds, and as a consequence, the smaller bid sizes for dealerquotes. To provide a concrete example, the issue sizes of <strong>in</strong>vestment-gradecorporate bonds are typically <strong>in</strong> the range of $150 to $500 million and thebid sizes of dealer quotes are usually valid for $5 million. Transact<strong>in</strong>g largertrade sizes on such bonds can drive the bid prices lower. In the U.S. Treasurymarket, execut<strong>in</strong>g a trade worth $100 million nom<strong>in</strong>al amount has anegligible market impact even for off-the-run securities. Clearly, the lack ofmarket depth when trad<strong>in</strong>g corporate bonds makes the task of manag<strong>in</strong>glarge corporate bond portfolios difficult. Other practical difficulties with


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 31regard to manag<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond portfolio relate to the difficulty off<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g offers on bonds that a portfolio manager may be will<strong>in</strong>g to buy orf<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g bids on bonds he or she may wish to sell. In particular, dur<strong>in</strong>g periodsof market turmoil, unw<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g “bad credits” may <strong>in</strong>cur considerableloss and, <strong>in</strong> worst-case situations, there may be no bids for them.Pric<strong>in</strong>g AnomaliesOther facts concern<strong>in</strong>g corporate bond trad<strong>in</strong>g relate to the dispersion ofprice quotes on bonds with very similar attributes. For <strong>in</strong>stance, corporatebond yields can vary significantly among issuers belong<strong>in</strong>g to the same corporatesector that have identical credit rat<strong>in</strong>g and comparable bond maturities.This makes the task of build<strong>in</strong>g generic-yield curves based on creditrat<strong>in</strong>g and the corporate sector difficult, if not impossible. However, thepractical value of such curves from a pric<strong>in</strong>g perspective is questionable. Toprovide a concrete example, the bid yields on dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated debt as of2 January 2003 for three BBB-rated issuers were as follows:General Motors (6.75 percent, 15JAN2006) Bid yield 5.752 percentDaimler Chrysler (7.25 percent, 18JAN2006) Bid yield 4.023 percentFord Motor <strong>Credit</strong> (6.875 percent, 01FEB2006) Bid yield 6.972 percentThere are several factors that <strong>in</strong>fluence large yield differences observedamong issuers belong<strong>in</strong>g to the same rat<strong>in</strong>g class. F<strong>in</strong>er rat<strong>in</strong>gs with<strong>in</strong> a rat<strong>in</strong>gcategory and the placement of issuers on credit watch tend to expla<strong>in</strong>some differences. The age of the bond, namely whether it was recentlyissued, also <strong>in</strong>fluences the yield differentials to a certa<strong>in</strong> extent due to theliquidity effect. Another factor that <strong>in</strong>fluences the yield of a corporate bondapart from the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g is the market perception regard<strong>in</strong>g the expectedrecovery amount on the bond <strong>in</strong> the event of issuer default. Even afteraccount<strong>in</strong>g for these factors, the yield differentials among issuers with identicalrat<strong>in</strong>gs can still be significant.These issues <strong>in</strong>dicate that the pric<strong>in</strong>g of corporate bonds can be rathertricky. Price quotes for corporate bonds obta<strong>in</strong>ed from different brokers ordealers tend to vary considerably. The lack of reliable pric<strong>in</strong>g sources forcorporate bonds makes the task of mark<strong>in</strong>g to market corporate bond portfoliosdifficult. In many cases, the bond prices supplied by the <strong>in</strong>dexprovider are commonly used. However, one has to bear <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d that whenexist<strong>in</strong>g bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio are sold, the realized market price can bequite different from the valuation price. Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g these differences, especiallyto clients, can be quite problematic.In order to improve the transparency of traded prices for corporatebonds, s<strong>in</strong>ce July 2002 the National Association of Securities Dealers


32 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS(NASD) has made it compulsory for all NASD member firms to report OTCtrades on corporate bonds that fall <strong>in</strong>to the category of TRACE-eligiblesecurity. TRACE stands for Trade Report<strong>in</strong>g and Compliance Eng<strong>in</strong>e;TRACE-eligible security covers most corporate bonds denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> U.S.dollars and registered with the Security and Exchange Commissions (SEC).Initial price dissem<strong>in</strong>ation to the public is currently limited to <strong>in</strong>vestmentgradebonds hav<strong>in</strong>g an issue size of $1 billion or more and some selectednon-<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade bonds.ROLE OF CORPORATE BONDS<strong>Corporate</strong> bonds are usually seen as offer<strong>in</strong>g economic enterprises an alternativefund<strong>in</strong>g source besides equity f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g and bank loans. Consider<strong>in</strong>gthat tak<strong>in</strong>g a bank loan or issu<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond to raise money can beregarded as a firm’s debt f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g options, either form of f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g willresult <strong>in</strong> the same debt-to-equity ratio for the firm. As a consequence, amicroeconomic view might suggest that the firm’s prospects will not dependon which form of debt f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g is used. However, from a macroeconomicperspective, strik<strong>in</strong>g the right balance between the two debt f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>goptions can have broader implications, especially for systemic risks faced bycountries. In this section, I exam<strong>in</strong>e these issues and highlight the importantrole corporate bonds play <strong>in</strong> a nation’s broader economic goals.F<strong>in</strong>ancial episodes <strong>in</strong> the recent past have shown that economies withwell-developed capital markets experience milder economic crises than thoselack<strong>in</strong>g this alternative fund<strong>in</strong>g source. In the case of Sweden, for example,a significant fall <strong>in</strong> real estate prices triggered a bank<strong>in</strong>g crisis <strong>in</strong> the early1990s primarily because of the large exposures banks had to the real estatesector. The corporate sector, however, which had access to a variety of nonbankfund<strong>in</strong>g sources, rebounded relatively quickly to trigger a speedyrecovery of the economy. Although the commitment of Swedish authoritiesto address the bank<strong>in</strong>g sector’s problem was a contribut<strong>in</strong>g factor, the diversityof fund<strong>in</strong>g sources for corporates also played an important role. TheUnited States had a similar experience dur<strong>in</strong>g the bank<strong>in</strong>g-related problemsaris<strong>in</strong>g from a fall <strong>in</strong> real estate value <strong>in</strong> the early 1990s. Aga<strong>in</strong>, access toalternative fund<strong>in</strong>g sources for corporates played a key role <strong>in</strong> the recoveryprocess. The experience of Australia dur<strong>in</strong>g the Asian crisis also provides an<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g case study. Despite its close trade and f<strong>in</strong>ancial ties to Asia, theAustralian economy experienced few signs of contagion arguably because ofwell-developed capital markets and a strong bank<strong>in</strong>g sector.Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g these examples, one may be tempted to argue thatalternative fund<strong>in</strong>g sources may not be necessary to soften the impact off<strong>in</strong>ancial crises. For <strong>in</strong>stance, one could argue <strong>in</strong> favor of exercis<strong>in</strong>g the


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 33policy options available to central banks, such as <strong>in</strong>ject<strong>in</strong>g liquidity <strong>in</strong>tothe bank<strong>in</strong>g system and reduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest rates, as a means of reduc<strong>in</strong>g theseverity of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis. Experience has shown that the recoveryfrom f<strong>in</strong>ancial shocks us<strong>in</strong>g these monetary tools may well depend onaccess to alternative fund<strong>in</strong>g sources. Specifically, <strong>in</strong> the case of the UnitedStates, fund<strong>in</strong>g from the capital markets for corporates almost dried up <strong>in</strong>the aftermath of the Russian default <strong>in</strong> August 1998. However, eas<strong>in</strong>g of<strong>in</strong>terest rates and <strong>in</strong>jection of liquidity <strong>in</strong>to the bank<strong>in</strong>g system by the FederalReserve ensured that corporates could ga<strong>in</strong> access to bank lend<strong>in</strong>gtemporarily until the capital markets recovered from the f<strong>in</strong>ancial shock.On the other hand, the experience of Japan has been quite the opposite.Despite the fact that the Bank of Japan has eased <strong>in</strong>terest rates progressivelyand <strong>in</strong>jected liquidity <strong>in</strong>to the bank<strong>in</strong>g sector, bank lend<strong>in</strong>g hasresponded little and economic recovery has been slow. An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>gobservation to make here is that <strong>in</strong> contrast to the United States, Japanesecorporates depend heavily on banks for fund<strong>in</strong>g and the nonbank lend<strong>in</strong>ghas not been sufficient to avoid a credit crunch.Alan Greenspan summed up his observations on the availability ofalternative fund<strong>in</strong>g sources for an economy as follows: “Multiple alternativesto transform an economy’s sav<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong>to capital <strong>in</strong>vestment offer a setof backup facilities should the primary form of <strong>in</strong>termediation fail.” 4 Hefurther argued that if anecdotal evidence suggests that diversity of fund<strong>in</strong>gsources provides <strong>in</strong>surance aga<strong>in</strong>st a f<strong>in</strong>ancial problem turn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to economywidedistress, then steps to foster the development of capital markets <strong>in</strong>those economies should be given priority. Moreover, diverse capital marketscompete with bank lend<strong>in</strong>g, and, as a consequence, the borrow<strong>in</strong>g costs forcorporates are lower dur<strong>in</strong>g normal times.Foster<strong>in</strong>g the development of capital markets, however, is a difficulttask especially if the necessary <strong>in</strong>frastructure required to support it is lack<strong>in</strong>g.This <strong>in</strong>cludes improved account<strong>in</strong>g standards, bankruptcy procedures,legal frameworks, and disclosure. Establish<strong>in</strong>g these becomes a preconditionfor the smooth function<strong>in</strong>g of capital markets.Although I highlighted the weaknesses and economic risks posed byreliance on bank lend<strong>in</strong>g as the primary source of fund<strong>in</strong>g, I did not questionwhy this practice tends to worsen economic crises. A recent paper byNils Hakansson identified two pr<strong>in</strong>cipal effects that contribute to this problem.5 First, the effects of misdirected government credit allocation preferenceswill tend to be magnified. Second, the absence of a sizable corporatebond market will aggravate the imperfections present <strong>in</strong> any f<strong>in</strong>ancial regulatorysystem. In the end, the <strong>in</strong>ferior risk assessment by the oversizedbank<strong>in</strong>g system together with other <strong>in</strong>herent weaknesses that may be present<strong>in</strong> the system will tend to overwhelm. This will then lead to productionovercapacity and nonperform<strong>in</strong>g loans, and f<strong>in</strong>ally to economic crisis.


34 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSHakansson argued further that government-<strong>in</strong>duced credit allocationpreferences and the lack of a developed corporate bond market sometimesforces unfavored <strong>in</strong>dustries to borrow abroad. When faith <strong>in</strong> the local currencybeg<strong>in</strong>s to fade, the scramble for foreign currency funds by these debtorsmay spark an economic crisis. Another problem that can arise due to the lackof a well-developed corporate bond market is that some of the nation’s basic<strong>in</strong>vestment needs, such as <strong>in</strong>frastructure projects, may be delayed or <strong>in</strong>adequatelyfunded. Worse still, <strong>in</strong> the absence of suitable <strong>in</strong>vestment alternatives,local <strong>in</strong>vestors might prefer to <strong>in</strong>vest abroad, thus depriv<strong>in</strong>g the nation ofscarce capital resources.When one understands the shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs of an overbear<strong>in</strong>g bank<strong>in</strong>g system,it becomes rather easy to see the role corporate bonds play <strong>in</strong> an economy.Besides serv<strong>in</strong>g as a backup fund<strong>in</strong>g source dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of creditcrunches, corporate bonds help <strong>in</strong> lower<strong>in</strong>g the fund<strong>in</strong>g costs for corporatesby compet<strong>in</strong>g with bank lend<strong>in</strong>g and offer <strong>in</strong>vestors alternative <strong>in</strong>vestmentopportunities. More important, however, is that a well-developed corporatebond market br<strong>in</strong>gs market discipl<strong>in</strong>e. The term market discipl<strong>in</strong>e broadlyrefers to the <strong>in</strong>frastructure and best market practices required to support thesmooth function<strong>in</strong>g of capital markets. This <strong>in</strong>cludes f<strong>in</strong>ancial report<strong>in</strong>gpractices for companies that are relevant and reliable, a strong communityof credit analysts, respected rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies that provide an impartial assessmentof the corporates, bankruptcy laws and courts to process the claims ofbond holders, and absence of <strong>in</strong>terference from governments.To put it <strong>in</strong> a nutshell, the existence of well-developed corporate bondmarkets reduces systemic risks and the severity of f<strong>in</strong>ancial crises. This isbecause such an environment is associated with greater account<strong>in</strong>g transparency,a larger community of credit analysts, the presence of respectedcredit rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies, and the existence of efficient procedures for corporatereorganization and liquidation. Because of the potential benefits stronglocal bond markets can br<strong>in</strong>g, policy makers and <strong>in</strong>ternational organizationshave embraced this pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, and efforts are under way to develop the localbond markets <strong>in</strong> many emerg<strong>in</strong>g economies. Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g these efforts, thedevelopment of a local corporate bond market <strong>in</strong> many emerg<strong>in</strong>g markets isstill constra<strong>in</strong>ed by several factors. Among these, the follow<strong>in</strong>g are important:A lack of liquidity <strong>in</strong> secondary markets and of a mean<strong>in</strong>gful <strong>in</strong>vestorbase with developed credit assessment skills.High costs of local issuance and crowd<strong>in</strong>g out by government bondissuance.The lack of a stable and large <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>vestor base and/or restrictionson their asset hold<strong>in</strong>gs.Restriction of access to local bond issuance to top-tier corporates <strong>in</strong>many countries.


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 35Despite these difficulties, considerable progress has been made <strong>in</strong> manyemerg<strong>in</strong>g markets <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g the corporate bond market as an alternativefund<strong>in</strong>g source for corporations.RELATIVE MARKET SIZEThe corporate bond market is large and diverse with daily trad<strong>in</strong>g volumeestimated to be close to $20 billion. The total market capitalization of globalcorporate bonds as of February 2003 was roughly USD 3,330 billion, anamount that is rather significant. In percentage terms, this amounts toroughly 19 percent of the market capitalization of Lehman’s global multiverse<strong>in</strong>dex. 6 To provide an <strong>in</strong>dication of the relative market size of corporatebonds versus other fixed-<strong>in</strong>come asset classes, Exhibit 3.1 gives abreakdown of the market capitalization of various asset classes <strong>in</strong> LehmanBrothers multiverse bond <strong>in</strong>dex.From Exhibit 3.1, one can see that the market capitalization of globalcorporate bonds is roughly the same as the market capitalization of mortgages.It is also useful to note here that asset-backed securities constituteonly 3 percent of the market capitalization of corporate bonds. This is quite<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g because it <strong>in</strong>dicates that the relative proportion of secured bondsEXHIBIT 3.1 Market Capitalization of Asset Classes (February 2003)Market CapitalizationDescription Number of Issues (USD million)Multiverse 11,360 17,907,223Government 2,212 9,868,696Treasuries 804 8,087,998Agencies 1,408 1,780,698<strong>Corporate</strong> 5,645 3,409,902Industrial 3,704 1,645,205Utility 755 385,255F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions 1,816 1,379,442Noncorporate 937 996,294Sovereign 423 419,159Supranational 234 301,312Others 280 275,624Securitized 2,567 3,632,338Mortgages 2,401 3,531,021Asset Backed 166 101,317Source: The Lehman Brothers Global Family of Indices. Copyright 2002, LehmanBrothers. Reproduced with permission from Lehman Brothers Inc. All rightsreserved.


36 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSissued by corporates is only around 3 percent. In terms of currency composition,roughly 60 percent of the corporate bonds are denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> U.S.dollars, 23 percent <strong>in</strong> euros, 9 percent <strong>in</strong> yen, 6 percent <strong>in</strong> pounds sterl<strong>in</strong>g,and the rest <strong>in</strong> other currencies. It is evident from this breakdown that U.S.dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated bonds constitute the bulk of the outstand<strong>in</strong>g corporatebonds.The forego<strong>in</strong>g observations suggest that corporate bonds as an assetclass offer <strong>in</strong>vestors a large pool of debt securities with significant marketcapitalization. Equally important from an <strong>in</strong>vestor’s perspective is to knowhow this market capitalization has evolved over time. Such an exam<strong>in</strong>ationreveals that the outstand<strong>in</strong>g issue size of corporate bonds has <strong>in</strong>creased significantlyover recent years. This may suggest that corporates are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>glyseek<strong>in</strong>g debt f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g through corporate bond issuance. For purposeof illustration, the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> outstand<strong>in</strong>g issue size of euro-denom<strong>in</strong>atedcorporate bonds over the period January 1999 to February 2003 was 48percent, and for U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated corporate bonds it was 42 percentover the same period.An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g observation to make here is that the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> marketcapitalization of corporate bonds happened dur<strong>in</strong>g a time when the supplyof U.S. Treasury debt was shr<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g. To provide some comparisons, themarket capitalization of <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bonds denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong>U.S. dollars rose from $690 billion as of end of 1992 to $1,730 billion asof end of 2002. Over the same period, the market capitalization of U.S.Treasuries (exclud<strong>in</strong>g T–bills) dropped from $1,790 billion to $1,700 billion.Exhibit 3.2 shows the evolution of the market capitalization of variousEXHIBIT 3.2Market capitalization (billion $)8,0007,0006,0005,0004,0003,0002,0001,000Market Capitalization of US Dollar-Denom<strong>in</strong>ated Asset ClassesMBSAgency<strong>Corporate</strong>Treasury0Jan.93 Jan.94 Jan.95 Jan.96 Jan.97 Jan.98 Jan.99 Jan.00 Jan.01 Jan.02Source: The Lehman Brothers Global Family of Indices. Copyright 2002, LehmanBrothers. Reproduced with permission from Lehman Brothers Inc. All rights reserved.


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 37U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated fixed-<strong>in</strong>come assets over the period January 1993to December 2002.HISTORICAL PERFORMANCEWhen <strong>in</strong>vestors evaluate the potential benefits of <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> an asset class,an analysis of the historical performance of the asset class <strong>in</strong> relation to othersis carried out as a rout<strong>in</strong>e exercise. Despite the fact that historical performanceis not an <strong>in</strong>dicator of future performance, analyz<strong>in</strong>g historicaldata has several advantages. For <strong>in</strong>stance, such an analysis can reveal relationshipsbetween different asset classes that are otherwise not obvious.Furthermore, an analysis of the historical returns data is required if onewishes to evaluate the potential risks associated with <strong>in</strong>vestment decisions.The advantages of exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g historical data when mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment decisionswas best summarized by William Sharpe: “Although it is always perilousto assume that the future will be like the past, it is at least <strong>in</strong>structiveto f<strong>in</strong>d out what the past was like. Experience suggests that for predict<strong>in</strong>gfuture values, historic data appear to be quite useful with respect to standarddeviations, reasonably useful for correlations, and virtually useless forexpected returns. For the latter, at least, other approaches are a must.” 7 Inthis section, I exam<strong>in</strong>e the historical performance of <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporatebonds as an asset class and compare this with the performance ofU.S. Treasuries and Standard & Poor’s 500 stock <strong>in</strong>dex.To compute different statistical measures of performance, the historicaldata used cover the 30-year period between January 1973 and January 2003.Monthly returns over this period for U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong>vestmentgradecorporate bonds (COR), U.S. Treasuries (UST), and Standard andPoor’s 500 <strong>in</strong>dex (S&P) were used to compute the relevant statistical measures.Exhibit 3.3 shows the statistical performance measures for differentEXHIBIT 3.3 Statistical Performance Measure for Asset Classes (January 1973 toJanuary 2003) aDescription UST COR S&PAnnualized return (%) 8.91 9.01 6.83Annualized volatility (%) 5.51 7.58 15.98Sharpe ratio 0.214 0.169 0.056Probability that annual return is positive (%) 94.50 85.90 72.40Conditional expected return if positive (%) 9.83 11.75 17.48Probability that annual return is negative (%) 5.50 14.10 27.60Conditional expected return if negative (%) 2.24 4.56 12.44a UST, U.S. Treasuries; COR, corporate bonds; S&P, Stand & Poor’s 500 <strong>in</strong>dex.


38 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 3.4 Correlation Matrix of MonthlyReturns (January 1973 to January 2003) aUST COR S&PUST 1.00 0.90 0.20COR 0.90 1.00 0.35S&P 0.20 0.35 1.00a UST, U.S. Treasuries; COR, corporate bonds;S&P, Standard & Poor’s 500 <strong>in</strong>dex.asset classes and Exhibit 3.4 shows the correlation between the monthlyreturns of different asset classes.The first three measures <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 3.3 are the standard risk–returnmeasures computed for different asset classes. In terms of annual returnsgenerated, the stock <strong>in</strong>dex was the worst performer. Although corporatesdid marg<strong>in</strong>ally better than U.S. Treasuries, if one accounts for the additionaltransaction costs <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> replicat<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond <strong>in</strong>dex, theannualized returns may be marg<strong>in</strong>ally below the Treasuries. The risk-freerate of return over the 30-year period is 7.73 percent (us<strong>in</strong>g 1-month libidrates). In terms of risk, the equity returns are more than two times riskierthan corporate bond returns and almost three times as risky as Treasuryreturns. Seen from the Sharpe ratio perspective, U.S. Treasuries were thebest performer over this period.The method used to estimate the other statistical measures given <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 3.3 is as follows. Probability that the annual return is positive ornegative is estimated by comput<strong>in</strong>g every month the total return over thepreced<strong>in</strong>g 12 months. These returns are then grouped <strong>in</strong>to negative andpositive returns, and the relative frequency of occurrence of a positive or anegative annual return is used to determ<strong>in</strong>e the probability of a positive ora negative return. The average return of each group is then determ<strong>in</strong>ed tocompute the conditional expected returns for a 1-year horizon. The historicalreturns over a 30-year period suggest that there is a 27.6 percent chancethat the return over any 1-year period on the S&P 500 <strong>in</strong>dex will be negative.Given that the return is negative dur<strong>in</strong>g a particular year, the expectedvalue of this negative return is 12.44 percent. For a portfolio that replicatesthe U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate <strong>in</strong>dex, theprobability of a negative return dur<strong>in</strong>g any year is only 14.1 percent and theconditional expected value of this return is 4.56 percent.Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Exhibit 3.4, we see that there is a very high correlationbetween <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bond returns and U.S. Treasuryreturns. This implies that there is little to ga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> terms of diversificationfrom hold<strong>in</strong>g a portfolio consist<strong>in</strong>g of U.S. Treasuries and corporatebonds. On the other hand, a portfolio consist<strong>in</strong>g of Treasury securities andequities offers the best diversification, with a correlation coefficient of .20.


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 39EXHIBIT 3.5 Statistical Performance Measure for Asset Classes (January 1975 toJanuary 2000) aDescription UST COR S&PAnnualized return (%) 9.02 9.83 12.81Annualized volatility (%) 5.69 7.77 14.90Sharpe ratio 0.098 0.176 0.292Probability that annual return is positive (%) 93.75 87.50 81.60Conditional expected return if positive (%) 10.27 12.41 17.77Probability that annual return is negative (%) 6.25 12.50 18.40Conditional expected return if negative (%) 2.21 4.31 8.13a UST, U.S. Treasuries; COR, <strong>Corporate</strong> bonds; S&P, Standard & Poor’s 500 <strong>in</strong>dex.The S&P 500 <strong>in</strong>dex returns and <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bond returnshave a correlation coefficient of .35, which is higher than the correlationbetween equity returns and Treasury returns. This is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g consider<strong>in</strong>gthat corporate bonds tend to perform badly whenever equityreturns are negative, and this expla<strong>in</strong>s why these two assets classes aremore correlated.Analyz<strong>in</strong>g historical data, though useful, can sometimes be mislead<strong>in</strong>g.To demonstrate this, the various performance statistics us<strong>in</strong>g monthly dataover the period January 1975 to January 2000 are presented <strong>in</strong> Exhibits 3.5and 3.6. The risk-free return over this period is 8.46 percent.The <strong>in</strong>ferences one would draw on future expected returns us<strong>in</strong>g thetwo data sets are quite different even though there is a significant time overlapbetween the two. The figures <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 3.5 suggest that equities outperformU.S. Treasuries by roughly 3.8 percent per annum over the longterm. Exhibit 3.3, on the other hand, suggests that equities underperformTreasuries by 2.1 percent over the long term. These observations confirm theremarks of William Sharpe that past returns are virtually useless for predict<strong>in</strong>gfuture returns. However, the volatility of returns is broadly similar acrossthe two time periods. For <strong>in</strong>stance, annual volatility of <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporatebonds is roughly <strong>in</strong> the range 7.5 to 7.7 percent. The correlationEXHIBIT 3.6 Correlation Matrix of MonthlyReturns (January 1975 to January 2000) aUST COR S&PUST 1.00 0.93 0.30COR 0.93 1.00 0.38S&P 0.30 0.38 1.00a UST, U.S. Treasuries; COR, corporate bonds;S&P, Standard & Poor’s 500 <strong>in</strong>dex.


40 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSbetween corporate bond returns and S&P 500 <strong>in</strong>dex returns is <strong>in</strong> the range.35 to .40, whereas the correlation between corporate bond returns andTreasury returns is around .90.An analysis of historical data also reveals that if the return of the<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bond <strong>in</strong>dex dur<strong>in</strong>g a year is negative, then theexpected value of this negative return is roughly 4.5 percent. The probabilityof a negative return dur<strong>in</strong>g any year for the corporate bond <strong>in</strong>dex isabout 14 percent. A f<strong>in</strong>al po<strong>in</strong>t of <strong>in</strong>terest is that among the three assetclasses considered here, the <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bond <strong>in</strong>dex has themost robust Sharpe ratio over both time periods. The implication is thatexcess returns over the risk-free rate have been more stable for corporatebonds than for Treasuries or equities dur<strong>in</strong>g the time periods considered here.THE CASE FOR CORPORATE BONDSThe corporate bond market represents a mature asset class with significantmarket capitalization and broad diversification across different sectors andcredit rat<strong>in</strong>gs. Look<strong>in</strong>g back over history, there is evidence that returns from<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bonds exhibit more stable Sharpe ratios thanreturns from U.S. Treasuries or equities. In addition, corporate bondreturns are more correlated than Treasury returns with equity <strong>in</strong>dex returns.The implication is that when the equity market rallies, corporate bonds performbetter than Treasuries, because credit spreads narrow. On the otherhand, a cont<strong>in</strong>ued fall <strong>in</strong> equity prices has an adverse impact on corporatebond returns. However, the downside risks of corporate bonds are considerablylower than for equities. As a result, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g corporate bonds <strong>in</strong> theasset composition mix of long-term <strong>in</strong>vestors offers <strong>in</strong>creased diversificationbenefits and reduces the fluctuations <strong>in</strong> annual returns. In this section, I discussthe advantages of <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> corporate bonds from the perspective oftwo <strong>in</strong>vestor groups: central bank reserve managers and pension fund plansponsors.Central Bank ReservesCurrency reserves, <strong>in</strong> general, are held by central banks for a variety of reasons,which <strong>in</strong>clude among others transaction needs, <strong>in</strong>tervention needs,and wealth diversification needs. Transaction needs are of m<strong>in</strong>or importanceto developed economies that have good access to <strong>in</strong>ternational capitalmarkets. On the other hand, for countries that have strict exchange ratecontrols, transaction needs may play a more important role. Interventionneeds arise when countries desire to have convertible currencies and at thesame time wish to reserve the power to <strong>in</strong>fluence exchange rates. This type


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 41of demand for reserves is considered by far the most important for thosecountries that have well-developed capital markets. Lastly, wealth effectsmay play some role <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al choice of the asset mix and currency compositionof the reserves. Dur<strong>in</strong>g recent years, the wealth effect has becomemore important as the need for central banks to be more transparent on therole and use of currency reserves, which are considered to be part of thenational sav<strong>in</strong>gs, has grown. Moreover, the size and growth of currencyreserves may provide signals to global f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets on the credibilityof the country’s monetary policy and creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess. In such a case, thereturn on the reserves held may not be <strong>in</strong>consequential. In fact, the desireto improve the return on reserves has been on the agenda of reserve managersacross the globe <strong>in</strong> recent years. In the discussion to follow, I highlightthe important factors lead<strong>in</strong>g to a change <strong>in</strong> focus from liquidity managementto returns management among reserve managers and <strong>in</strong>dicate whycorporate bonds as an asset class are an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment alternativeto government bonds when higher return on reserves becomes an explicitobjective.Chang<strong>in</strong>g Objectives Foreign currency reserves play a crucial role <strong>in</strong> the liquiditymanagement by countries that do not always have ready and <strong>in</strong>expensiveaccess to <strong>in</strong>ternational capital markets. Consider<strong>in</strong>g its importance,central banks have held a significant proportion of their foreign exchangereserves <strong>in</strong> a portfolio of short-dated f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>struments to facilitate liquiditymanagement. This portfolio, usually referred to as the liquidity portfolio,serves the purposes of foreign currency debt servic<strong>in</strong>g, offsett<strong>in</strong>g balanceof payments, and ensur<strong>in</strong>g the smooth function<strong>in</strong>g of the foreignexchange markets. Among these, the need for liquidity <strong>in</strong> a central bankreserves portfolio is usually dom<strong>in</strong>ated by the role <strong>in</strong>tervention plays <strong>in</strong> thecentral bank’s management of reserves. However, this view is chang<strong>in</strong>g as aconsequence of the liberalization of capital markets and the growth of <strong>in</strong>ternationalf<strong>in</strong>ancial flows, which render foreign currency <strong>in</strong>tervention hav<strong>in</strong>gat best only a transitory impact on the exchange rate of a given country.Moreover, central banks realize that they have a greater number of optionsavailable to meet fund<strong>in</strong>g requirements. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> the 1980s, currency<strong>in</strong>tervention was usually done <strong>in</strong> spot markets, lead<strong>in</strong>g to a need for cashliquidity that was funded by the sale of securities. The existence of an activerepo market, at least for government securities, has called <strong>in</strong>to question theneed to <strong>in</strong>vest a significant proportion of foreign currency reserves <strong>in</strong> shortdated<strong>in</strong>struments.In the past, central banks were less concerned about the relative proportionof reserves held <strong>in</strong> the liquidity portfolio because liquidity managementwas regarded as be<strong>in</strong>g the motive for hold<strong>in</strong>g reserves. In recent years,this notion has been challenged as a result of experiences of countries faced


42 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSwith economic crises. Specifically, the series of crises <strong>in</strong> the emerg<strong>in</strong>g marketsdur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s found several countries short of foreign currency reserves,a shortage that often constra<strong>in</strong>ed subsequent policy choices and <strong>in</strong> severalcases made even worse the recessions that followed. On the other hand,countries with significant levels of reserves (Ch<strong>in</strong>a and Hong Kong) wereable to hold their exchange rates steady despite a regional crisis. This experienceled to the general impression that <strong>in</strong>creased capital flows require centralbanks to hold more reserves than when capital flows were smaller orsubject to controls. In fact, many reserve managers now share the op<strong>in</strong>ionthat emerg<strong>in</strong>g market countries need to hold much larger levels of reservesthan previously felt necessary.How large the reserves need to be depends on factors such as volatilityof the real or the f<strong>in</strong>ancial economy, the level of current account deficits, andwhether the country is operat<strong>in</strong>g under a fixed or a float<strong>in</strong>g exchange rateregime. Furthermore, the globalization of capital markets has made the taskof predict<strong>in</strong>g volatility of capital flows difficult, and, as a consequence, thelevel of reserves required to absorb these fluctuations is higher. Another reasonfor hold<strong>in</strong>g large reserves is the observation that the size of reserves is akey element determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sovereign credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs. Foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors, lack<strong>in</strong>gany firm basis on which to assess the adequacy of a country’s reserves, maysimply look at the level of reserves relative to that <strong>in</strong> comparable countries.Although higher levels of reserves are considered desirable, current op<strong>in</strong>ionamong central bankers is that there is no objective way of calibrat<strong>in</strong>g thedesired level of currency reserves for a country.As a consequence of the desire to hold larger reserves, foreign currencyreserves have grown significantly <strong>in</strong> many countries despite the fact thatglobal growth has weakened over this period. In some countries, reserveshave gone to 200 percent of short-term foreign debt and are still ris<strong>in</strong>g. Theaccumulation of foreign currency reserves has been high on the agenda ofmany central banks, and as this gathers momentum, the debate on the<strong>in</strong>vestment objectives of the reserves is also ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g importance. One consequenceof reserve buildup <strong>in</strong> hard currencies is that it <strong>in</strong>curs costs <strong>in</strong> realresources. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the budget cost of pay<strong>in</strong>g higher <strong>in</strong>terest rates fordomestic borrow<strong>in</strong>gs employed to purchase lower yield<strong>in</strong>g hard currencyassets is a transfer of real resources. For this reason, the decision to buildup currency reserves <strong>in</strong>volves a difficult cost–benefit analysis.This br<strong>in</strong>gs up the follow<strong>in</strong>g question: What is the cost of hold<strong>in</strong>greserves? This is a difficult question and there is no clear answer. If the benefitsof hold<strong>in</strong>g reserves are hard to quantify, the costs are even harder tomeasure. If foreign borrow<strong>in</strong>g is used to build up reserves, countries <strong>in</strong>effect pay the foreign credit spread over U.S. Treasuries or comparablepaper. This spread, which is negligible for borrowers at the upper end of the<strong>in</strong>vestment grade, is quite significant as the sovereign rat<strong>in</strong>g becomes more


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 43speculative. However, this calculation might overstate the cost of reservesby fail<strong>in</strong>g to take <strong>in</strong>to account the possible effect of reserve levels on theassessment of sovereign credit rat<strong>in</strong>g. On the assumption that higher reservelevels lead to an improved credit rat<strong>in</strong>g, both domestic and foreign borrow<strong>in</strong>gcosts will be reduced. Furthermore, one can conjecture that the corporatesector <strong>in</strong> a country with high reserve levels may also benefit by be<strong>in</strong>gable to borrow at lower <strong>in</strong>terest rates <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets.An alternative way to measure the cost of hold<strong>in</strong>g reserves is to stressthe opportunity costs and attempt to analyze the macroeconomic consequencesof reserve accumulation. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the opportunity costs ofreserves accumulated from a succession of current account surpluses are thereturns on forgone domestic <strong>in</strong>vestment. However, the marg<strong>in</strong>al productivityof capital is hard to measure.Although additional costs <strong>in</strong>curred <strong>in</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g higher reserve levelsare difficult to measure, reserve managers are becom<strong>in</strong>g conscious of theneed to <strong>in</strong>crease return on reserves as a means to reduce the costs whenreserves held are well <strong>in</strong> excess of the liquidity requirements of a centralbank. This has prompted many central banks to regard the reserve managementoperation to a limited extent as a profit center and the reservesthemselves as a store of wealth that generates revenue. With this change <strong>in</strong>perception, the reserve management function has taken over the additionaltask of an asset management function where the assets under managementare the currency reserves of the central bank.Composition of Currency Reserves Official foreign currency reserves held by centralbanks as of end of 2001 amounted to $2,021 billion, and roughly 75percent of this was held <strong>in</strong> dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated assets. 8 The high dollar component<strong>in</strong> the reserves <strong>in</strong>dicates that the U.S. dollar cont<strong>in</strong>ued to be the ma<strong>in</strong>reserve currency for central banks; the euro was still well beh<strong>in</strong>d with roughly14 percent share. Hav<strong>in</strong>g made the case why reserve managers target higherreturns on reserves, it will be of <strong>in</strong>terest to exam<strong>in</strong>e the <strong>in</strong>struments <strong>in</strong> whichthe official reserves are <strong>in</strong>vested to achieve the higher return target. This givesan <strong>in</strong>dication of the extent to which the desire to generate higher returns onreserves is implemented <strong>in</strong> practice. Unfortunately, f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g good data on thecomposition of currency reserves at the <strong>in</strong>strument level is extremely difficult.Consider<strong>in</strong>g that the dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated assets make up 75 percent of thereserves, I focus on identify<strong>in</strong>g the composition of the dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>atedreserve hold<strong>in</strong>gs at the <strong>in</strong>strument-level. Exhibit 3.7 shows the <strong>in</strong>strumentlevelcomposition of the U.S. dollar reserves as of March 2000.Data on identified official hold<strong>in</strong>gs of dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated assets given <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 3.7 suggest that U.S. Treasury securities represented more than half(58 percent) of the dollar hold<strong>in</strong>gs of central banks. Identified dollar hold<strong>in</strong>gs,however, aggregate to a sum well short of the estimated dollar reserves


44 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 3.7 Instrument Composition of U.S. Dollar Reserves at End of March2000 (In Billions of U.S. Dollars)Short term Long term TotalTreasury securities 165 492 657 (58%)Other assets 262 211 565 (42%)Deposits <strong>in</strong> the United States 32 —Money market paper <strong>in</strong> theUnited States 104 —Offshore deposits 126 —Agency securities — 91<strong>Corporate</strong> bonds — 12Equity — 96Total 427 703 1130 (100%)Memorandum items: Share of Treasurysecurities <strong>in</strong> assets of the given maturity 39% 70%Total estimated U.S. dollar reserves atend of 1999 1359Source: Robert McCauley and Ben Fung, “Choos<strong>in</strong>g Instruments <strong>in</strong> <strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> DollarForeign Exchange Reserves,” BIS Quarterly Review, March 2003, p. 41, Table 1.Copyright 2003, Bank for International Settlements. Repr<strong>in</strong>ted with permission.($1,130 billion versus $1,359 billion). Under the assumption that the officialestimates of U.S. Treasury hold<strong>in</strong>gs by central banks are accurate, U.S. Treasurysecurities constitute only 48 percent of the dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated assets. Still,the relative proportion of Treasury securities <strong>in</strong> dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated reservehold<strong>in</strong>gs is quite high. Also of <strong>in</strong>terest to note here is that the next asset class<strong>in</strong> which significant <strong>in</strong>vestments are made is <strong>in</strong> equities. However, March2000 was the period when equities reached their highs, and s<strong>in</strong>ce then theyhave decl<strong>in</strong>ed significantly. Although no official data are yet available, onemight guess that the relative proportion of equities <strong>in</strong> dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>atedreserve assets must have decl<strong>in</strong>ed considerably as of the end of 2002.The <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> corporate bonds, an asset class of <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the contextof this book, is very small, amount<strong>in</strong>g to less than 1 percent of the estimateddollar reserves. Apart from equities, the non-Treasury component oflong-term dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated reserves has been primarily <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> U.S.agency securities or bonds issued by supranationals. This is an <strong>in</strong>dication thatreserve managers cont<strong>in</strong>ue to be wary of tak<strong>in</strong>g on credit risk as a means ofimprov<strong>in</strong>g the return on reserves. This is because loss result<strong>in</strong>g from creditrisk is still considered a taboo among central banks. Based on anecdotal evidence,target<strong>in</strong>g higher return on reserves has been achieved ma<strong>in</strong>ly by<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the duration of the reserves portfolio <strong>in</strong> recent years. In a fall<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>terest rate environment, this strategy so far has been quite reward<strong>in</strong>g.


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 45The composition of dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated assets at the <strong>in</strong>strument level<strong>in</strong>dicates that there is not much diversification <strong>in</strong> terms of asset classes <strong>in</strong>the reserves portfolio. To a limited extent, the overreliance on Treasuries isa reflection of the lack of adequate skills among reserve managers to managerisks other than duration. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong>clusion of mortgage-backedsecurities requires the ability to model, measure, and manage prepaymentrisks. Includ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bonds requires the ability tomeasure and manage credit risk. Although lack of skills is a constra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gfactor, it is not the only constra<strong>in</strong>t faced by central banks. Other reasonscommonly cited by central bankers <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>adequate risk managementsystems, lack of an <strong>in</strong>centive structure, and high job rotation among reservemanagers, which hampers develop<strong>in</strong>g expertise.If <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g return on reserves is regarded as an explicit objective, durationextension as a means to achieve higher returns <strong>in</strong> a low-<strong>in</strong>terest-rateenvironment will expose central banks to substantial downside risks. In thissituation, pursu<strong>in</strong>g higher returns would necessitate review<strong>in</strong>g the asset compositionof the reserves and f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g an appropriate trade-off between thelevel of market risk and credit risk that is be<strong>in</strong>g taken.Why <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong>s? In pursuit of the objective of improv<strong>in</strong>g return onreserves, most central banks face the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment constra<strong>in</strong>t: littleor no risk of a negative return over a 1-year <strong>in</strong>vestment period. This constra<strong>in</strong>tis ma<strong>in</strong>ly a consequence of the greater public scrut<strong>in</strong>y of the <strong>in</strong>vestmentpractices of a central bank and the negative publicity <strong>in</strong>vestment-relatedlosses on reserves are subject to. To reduce the risk of a negative return,most central banks rule out the <strong>in</strong>clusion of equities <strong>in</strong> the reserves portfoliobecause the volatility of equity returns is quite high. This leaves centralbanks with primarily two alternatives for improv<strong>in</strong>g the return on reserves:Either take more <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk or take more credit risk. I will argue that<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g corporate bonds <strong>in</strong> the reserves portfolio, which amounts to tak<strong>in</strong>gmore credit risk, is a better alternative to target<strong>in</strong>g higher returns without<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the downside risk potential.In exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the historical performance of different asset classes, Icompared the performance of <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bonds aga<strong>in</strong>stU.S. Treasuries. The corporate bond <strong>in</strong>vestment universe I considered<strong>in</strong>cluded bonds rated BBB-m<strong>in</strong>us and above and maturities up to 30 years.Even if one assumes that central banks will diversify <strong>in</strong>to corporate bondsto target higher returns, most central banks would be unwill<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong>bonds rated below s<strong>in</strong>gle-A. Furthermore, the <strong>in</strong>vestment maturities areusually restricted to be below 10 years even for Treasury securities. 9 Tomake the <strong>in</strong>vestment performance comparisons between corporates andTreasuries mean<strong>in</strong>gful <strong>in</strong> a central bank context, I restrict the corporatebond universe to be A-m<strong>in</strong>us or better and the <strong>in</strong>vestment maturity to be


46 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 3.8 Performance of One- to Five-Year Sector Duration-Neutral <strong>Portfolios</strong>(January 1999 to January 2003)Annualized MarketAnnual return volatility capitalization aDescription (%) (%) ($ billion)<strong>Corporate</strong>s A-m<strong>in</strong>us or better 7.77 2.45 410U.S. Treasuries 6.86 2.83 840a Market capitalization as of January 2003.between 1 and 5 years. Exhibit 3.8 shows the performance of durationneutralportfolios, one replicat<strong>in</strong>g the 1- to 5-year sector of dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>atedcorporate bonds rated A-m<strong>in</strong>us or better and the other replicat<strong>in</strong>g the1- to 5-year sector of U.S. Treasuries over the period January 1999 toJanuary 2003. The correlation between the monthly returns of these twoportfolios over this period is .92.The figures <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 3.8 are quite <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g because they show thatcorporate bonds outperformed Treasuries dur<strong>in</strong>g a period when equity marketsfell significantly and credit spreads widened. Moreover, this outperformancewas accompanied by lower volatility of returns of the corporatebond portfolio compared to the volatility of returns of a Treasury portfoliowith identical duration. The implication is that long-term <strong>in</strong>vestors are adequatelycompensated for the additional risks <strong>in</strong>volved when <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>corporate bonds. The additional risks <strong>in</strong>clude credit risk and liquidity risk,and these appear to demand a significant risk premium <strong>in</strong> recent years follow<strong>in</strong>gthe Asian and Russian f<strong>in</strong>ancial crises.Although it is tempt<strong>in</strong>g to argue that <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> corporate bonds willbr<strong>in</strong>g diversification benefits to the reserves portfolio, note that the correlationbetween corporate bond portfolio returns and Treasury portfolioreturns is greater than .9. Such a high level of correlation implies that it isdifficult to motivate <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> corporate bonds from the diversificationperspective. A better justification for <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> corporate bonds by centralbanks is that it lowers the volatility of returns of the reserves portfolio whileat the same time provid<strong>in</strong>g long-term yield enhancement over Treasuries. 10To compute the downside risk of <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> corporate bonds asopposed to Treasuries on a duration-neutral basis, one can exam<strong>in</strong>e theworst-case underperformance of the corporate bond portfolio relative tothe Treasury portfolio over any 1-year period. Based on the historical datacover<strong>in</strong>g the period January 1999 to January 2003, the worst-case underperformancewas 80 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. This occurred dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1-year periodbetween 1 August 2001 and 31 July 2002, a period of widen<strong>in</strong>g creditspreads after the tragic events of the September 11 attack.


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 47The historical data used to compare relative performances of corporateand Treasury portfolios are representative of a recessionary time period. Ishowed by exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g data over this period that the corporate bond portfoliooutperformed a duration-neutral Treasury portfolio. In a period ofeconomic expansion when <strong>in</strong>terest rates are bound to <strong>in</strong>crease, corporatesmay still offer scope for outperform<strong>in</strong>g Treasuries. This is because economicexpansions are associated with <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g equity prices, and this has theeffect of narrow<strong>in</strong>g the credit spreads for corporate bonds. Under this scenario,the potential downside risk for a corporate bond portfolio is lowerthan for a Treasury portfolio of similar duration. These effects are morepronounced for <strong>in</strong>vestment maturities <strong>in</strong> the short end of the yield curve, asector that happens to be the natural choice for central banks.Pension FundsPension funds can be broadly classified <strong>in</strong>to def<strong>in</strong>ed contribution schemesand def<strong>in</strong>ed benefit schemes. A def<strong>in</strong>ed contribution scheme <strong>in</strong>volves a contractualcommitment to contribute a certa<strong>in</strong> amount of money to a pensionplan, with no guarantee as to how much money will be <strong>in</strong> the plan at retirementand no guarantee as to the annual retirement benefit the employee willreceive. A def<strong>in</strong>ed benefit scheme, on the other hand, makes no guaranteeas to the amount of the contribution the corporation will make, but it doesguarantee a def<strong>in</strong>ed annual retirement benefit to the employee. It is evidentfrom this def<strong>in</strong>ition that <strong>in</strong> a def<strong>in</strong>ed contribution scheme the employeebears all market risk and captures all the rewards <strong>in</strong> the event of strongmarket performance. In a def<strong>in</strong>ed benefit scheme, however, the corporationbears the market risk and suffers the penalty of <strong>in</strong>creased pension contributionsif pension assets do not meet the liabilities. In this section, I focusma<strong>in</strong>ly on the def<strong>in</strong>ed benefit scheme.The objective of a def<strong>in</strong>ed benefit pension fund’s asset allocation policyis to fully fund accrued pension liabilities at the lowest cost to the plansponsor subject to an acceptable level of risk. The major risk plan sponsorsface is the higher contributions that will be required if the pension assets failto generate returns that cover the actuarial liabilities. This risk is referred toas surplus risk, which is the risk that the assets will fall short of liabilities.To reduce this risk, pension fund asset allocation decisions require an assetliabilitymodel<strong>in</strong>g framework. A pension scheme is said to be fully fundedif the market value of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial assets <strong>in</strong> the pension fund is equal to thepresent value of the pension liabilities. Clearly, the method used to computethe present value of assets and liabilities has an <strong>in</strong>fluence on the deficit orsurplus that is be<strong>in</strong>g reported.In the past, account<strong>in</strong>g practices dealt with the problem of fluctuat<strong>in</strong>g marketvalue of assets by smooth<strong>in</strong>g them out. The actuarial liabilities of a pension


48 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSfund are usually measured on the basis of the projected unit credit method.Comput<strong>in</strong>g actuarial liabilities us<strong>in</strong>g this method requires mak<strong>in</strong>g assumptionsregard<strong>in</strong>g mortality and disability rates, progression of salaries and future <strong>in</strong>flationrates, long-term return on assets and applicable discount rates, and projectionsfor withdraw<strong>in</strong>g participants and retirements. The applicable discountrate <strong>in</strong> the past was chosen to be the effective yield on long-term bonds andequities, and the discount rate used displayed very little variations from oneyear to another. Such an approach to valu<strong>in</strong>g assets and liabilities of pensionfunds has the effect of reduc<strong>in</strong>g the volatility of the surplus, and consequentlythe surplus risk (or equivalently, deficit risk) was kept to a m<strong>in</strong>imum.More recently, the account<strong>in</strong>g practices for report<strong>in</strong>g and deal<strong>in</strong>g witha pension fund deficit or surplus have undergone dramatic changes. 11 Therecommendations under International Account<strong>in</strong>g Standard 19 for def<strong>in</strong>edbenefits scheme are the follow<strong>in</strong>g:Current service cost should be recognized as an expense.All companies should use the projected unit credit method to measuretheir pension expense and pension obligation.The rate used to discount postemployment benefit obligation should bedeterm<strong>in</strong>ed by reference to market yields at balance sheet date on highqualitycorporate bonds of maturity comparable to plan obligations.Postemployment benefit obligations should be measured on a basis thatreflects (a) estimated future salary <strong>in</strong>creases, (b) the benefits set out <strong>in</strong>the terms of the plan at the balance sheet date, and (c) estimated futurepension <strong>in</strong>creases.If the net cumulative unrecognized actuarial ga<strong>in</strong>s and losses exceed thegreater of 10 percent of the present value of the plan obligation or 10percent of the fair value of plan assets, that excess must be amortizedover a period not longer than the estimated average rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g work<strong>in</strong>glives of employees participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the plan. Faster amortization ispermitted.Plan assets should be measured at fair value.These changes <strong>in</strong> account<strong>in</strong>g practices are <strong>in</strong>tended to serve the follow<strong>in</strong>gobjectives:The employer’s f<strong>in</strong>ancial statements reflect the assets and liabilities aris<strong>in</strong>gfrom the retirement benefit obligations and any related fund<strong>in</strong>gmeasured at current market prices.The operat<strong>in</strong>g costs of provid<strong>in</strong>g retirement benefits are recognized <strong>in</strong>the periods <strong>in</strong> which the benefits are earned by employees.F<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g costs and any other changes <strong>in</strong> the value of the assets and liabilitiesare recognized <strong>in</strong> the periods <strong>in</strong> which they arise.


The <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market 49Implications for Pension Funds The valuation of pension liabilities us<strong>in</strong>g adiscount rate based on current yield of a high-quality corporate bond(AA-rated is the one used) of comparable maturity as the plan obligationhas important implications for surplus risk. In particular, use of the marketvalue of pension assets and the discount rate based on the current yield ofan AA-rated corporate bond for comput<strong>in</strong>g actuarial liabilities can lead togreater volatility of the pension fund surplus. To see why this may be thecase, consider the case where the pension assets are primarily <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong>equities. Dur<strong>in</strong>g period of recession, equity markets perform badly and themarket value of pension assets decl<strong>in</strong>es. <strong>Bond</strong> yields, on the other hand,decl<strong>in</strong>e dur<strong>in</strong>g this period when central banks ease monetary policy. As aconsequence, the appropriate discount rates to be used for comput<strong>in</strong>g thepresent value of actuarial liabilities are lower, and this <strong>in</strong> turn leads to higherpension liabilities. The comb<strong>in</strong>ation of a lower market value for assets anda higher value for liabilities leads to a large deficit <strong>in</strong> the pension scheme ifone assumes that it was fully funded to beg<strong>in</strong> with.Dur<strong>in</strong>g economic expansions, the opposite is true. Large surpluses canbe built up if the pension assets are primarily made up of equities. Thesesurpluses can quickly turn <strong>in</strong>to deficits <strong>in</strong> a matter of a few years of fall<strong>in</strong>gequity markets. In fact, many pension funds have suffered from overexposureto equity markets <strong>in</strong> recent years and are currently underfunded. In theUnited K<strong>in</strong>gdom, for <strong>in</strong>stance, a typical pension fund has more than 60 percentexposure to equities, although <strong>in</strong> the United States this percentage issomewhat lower.Reduc<strong>in</strong>g the exposure to equities and simultaneously <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g theexposure to corporate bonds <strong>in</strong> pension funds is a natural hedge to reducethe surplus risk. Although <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the proportion of corporate bonds (orother fixed-<strong>in</strong>come securities) results <strong>in</strong> a reduction <strong>in</strong> surplus risk, pensionplan sponsors also have to ensure that the expected return on assets is <strong>in</strong>l<strong>in</strong>e with the growth rate <strong>in</strong> real earn<strong>in</strong>gs. This is because <strong>in</strong>vestment returnsdeterm<strong>in</strong>e the rate at which contributions <strong>in</strong>to the pension fund accumulateover time, and the growth rate <strong>in</strong> real earn<strong>in</strong>gs determ<strong>in</strong>es the size of contributions<strong>in</strong>to the scheme and the pension liability at the retirement date.Investments <strong>in</strong> equities or property provide better hedge for the growth rate<strong>in</strong> real earn<strong>in</strong>gs, whereas <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> bonds reduces the surplus risk. Hence,the optimal asset allocation for a pension fund depends on the trade-offbetween surplus risk and the expected return on assets.In general, the asset allocation decision critically depends on theassumed risk premiums for different assets. If one believes that the <strong>in</strong>flationrates and equity risk premium will be lower for this decade than for the previoustwo decades, pension sponsors are better off <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g a greater proportionof the pension assets <strong>in</strong> fixed-<strong>in</strong>come securities. With<strong>in</strong> the fixed<strong>in</strong>comeasset class, corporate bonds offer greater opportunity to <strong>in</strong>crease


50 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSexpected returns on the pension assets and, consequently, lower the contributionrate for pension plan sponsors. This is because of the higher yields<strong>in</strong>vestors demand for hold<strong>in</strong>g this asset class as opposed to governmentbonds. Furthermore, the higher correlation between corporate bond returnsand equity returns observed <strong>in</strong> the historical data suggests that <strong>in</strong> the eventof a strong equity market performance, corporate bonds provide a greaterupside than government bonds.QUESTIONS1. What are the different forms of bond collateralization used for securitization?2. What are the major <strong>in</strong>vestment risks fac<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond <strong>in</strong>vestor?3. What factors contribute to higher trad<strong>in</strong>g costs for corporate bonds?4. A corporate bond portfolio has an average duration of 2.5 years andaverage bid–ask yield spread of 5 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. If the annual portfolioturnover is 125 percent, compute the costs aris<strong>in</strong>g from trad<strong>in</strong>g.5. What role does corporate bonds play <strong>in</strong> an economy?6. What purpose does historical performance analysis serve?7. What are the major challenges faced by reserve managers <strong>in</strong> centralbanks?8. How would you justify an <strong>in</strong>creased exposure to corporate bonds forthe reserves portfolio?9. How do the new account<strong>in</strong>g rules for pension fund report<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>fluencethe asset allocation decision for pension funds?10. What is surplus risk and how can it be reduced?


CHAPTER 4Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong>In broad terms, portfolio management refers to the process of manag<strong>in</strong>g aportfolio’s risk relative to a benchmark with the purpose of either track<strong>in</strong>gor add<strong>in</strong>g value aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark. In the context of manag<strong>in</strong>g a corporatebond portfolio, the major sources of risk are a change <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terestrates or a change <strong>in</strong> the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the bond issuer. In addition, bondhold<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> currencies other than the portfolio’s base currency are exposedto exchange rate risk as well. The price risk result<strong>in</strong>g from a change <strong>in</strong> thecredit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the bond issuer is usually attributed to credit risk, whereasprice risks result<strong>in</strong>g from a change <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terest rate and exchange rate areclassified under market risk. In the event that the portfolio and the benchmarkhave different exposures to the various risk factors that <strong>in</strong>fluence theprice dynamics of corporate bonds, the portfolio’s returns and the benchmark’sreturns can deviate from one other. Clearly, the job of a portfolio manageris to exploit the upside potential when deviat<strong>in</strong>g from the benchmarkneutral position while controll<strong>in</strong>g the downside risk. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that aprerequisite for controll<strong>in</strong>g the downside risk is the ability to measure riskexposures relative to the benchmark, the implementation of an appropriaterisk model is a logical first step <strong>in</strong> this process.In this chapter, I first discuss different measures that can be used toquantify <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk. Subsequently, I develop a risk model that can beused to quantify the market risk of the corporate bond portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st thebenchmark.INTEREST RATE RISKIn this section, I discuss the impact of <strong>in</strong>terest rate changes on the price ofsecurities that provide future cash flows. Because the present value of suchsecurities is the discounted value of the future cash flows, changes to the<strong>in</strong>terest rates change the appropriate discounts to be used for the cash flows.As a consequence, the price of the security changes. In some cases, changesto the <strong>in</strong>terest rate can change the cash flows themselves. This is the case for51


52 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSbonds with embedded options. In this section, I discuss various risk measuresthat are commonly used to quantify the price sensitivity of debt <strong>in</strong>strumentsto changes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terest rate curve.Modified DurationThe price of any security that offers future cash flows depends on the currentterm structure of <strong>in</strong>terest rates. Changes to the <strong>in</strong>terest rate term structureresult <strong>in</strong> a change <strong>in</strong> the price of the <strong>in</strong>terest rate-dependent security.The price of a corporate bond, which provides future cash flows, is thereforesensitive to changes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terest rate term structure. It is commonpractice to refer to the term structure of <strong>in</strong>terest rates simply as the yieldcurve. The price sensitivity of the bond is usually a function of how theyield curve’s shape changes.To measure the price sensitivity to parallel shifts of the yield curve, themost commonly used risk measure is modified duration. In simple terms,modified duration is the percentage change <strong>in</strong> a bond’s price for a 100-basispo<strong>in</strong>t parallel shift <strong>in</strong> the yield curve, assum<strong>in</strong>g that the bond’s cash flowsdo not change when the yield curve shifts. Mathematically, modified durationis def<strong>in</strong>ed as the negative of the percentage change <strong>in</strong> price given a 100-basis po<strong>in</strong>ts change <strong>in</strong> yield to maturity:D 1 dP dirtyP dirty dy(4.1)In this equation, P dirty is the dirty price (quoted or clean price plus accrued<strong>in</strong>terest) of the bond for $1 face value, which I will simply refer to as theprice of the bond. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that yield to maturity is the <strong>in</strong>terest rate thatmakes the present value of a bond’s cash flows equal to its price, theprice–yield relationship for a bond is given byP dirty aNi1Cf i(1 y/n) nt i(4.2)In equation (4.2), Cf i is the ith cash flow at time t i and n is the number ofcoupons per annum. From equations (4.1) and (4.2), the modified durationof the bond is given byD 1(1 y/n)1P dirtyNt i Cf ia (1 y/n) nt ii1(4.3)


Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong> 53ConvexityFor estimat<strong>in</strong>g price changes result<strong>in</strong>g from a small parallel shift of the yieldcurve, modified duration provides a reasonable approximation. When theyield curve shifts are larger, however, modified duration fails to provide agood approximation of price changes. This is because the price–yield relationshipis nonl<strong>in</strong>ear as modeled by equation (4.2). Also, modified durationcaptures only the effects of the first-order term <strong>in</strong> a Taylor series expansionof this nonl<strong>in</strong>ear function. Includ<strong>in</strong>g higher order terms of the Taylor seriesexpansion can provide an improved estimate of the price change result<strong>in</strong>gfrom yield curve shifts. Common practice is to <strong>in</strong>clude the second-orderterm, which is referred to as convexity. Convexity captures the curvature ofthe price–yield relationship; <strong>in</strong> mathematical terms, it is def<strong>in</strong>ed asC 1P dirtyd 2 P dirtydy 2(4.4)Us<strong>in</strong>g the price–yield relationship (4.2) and the convexity def<strong>in</strong>ition givenby equation (4.4), one can show that the convexity of the bond satisfies thefollow<strong>in</strong>g equation:C 1 1(1 y/n) 2 P dirtyNt i (1 nt i ) Cf ia n (1 y/n) nt ii1(4.5)Approximat<strong>in</strong>g Price ChangesThese two risk measures—modified duration and convexity—provide agood approximation of a bond’s price change result<strong>in</strong>g from a change <strong>in</strong> theyield to maturity of that bond. Both measures are widely used <strong>in</strong> the contextof bond portfolio management to control <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk. For<strong>in</strong>stance, us<strong>in</strong>g modified duration and convexity measures, one obta<strong>in</strong>s theapproximate price change of a bond due to a change <strong>in</strong> the yield to maturityby an amount y:¢P dirty P dirty D ¢y 0.5P dirty C ¢y 2(4.6)It is important to note that both modified duration and convexity providelocal approximations to the price–yield relationship of a bond. Hence, whenthe yield changes are large, the estimated price change us<strong>in</strong>g equation (4.6)may not be very accurate. However, for the purposes of model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terestrate risk, these local approximations are usually good, as market-drivenyield changes are usually not very large (typically less than 50 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts).


54 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS<strong>Bond</strong>s with Embedded OptionsWhen comput<strong>in</strong>g modified duration and convexity measures, one assumesthat future cash flows are not altered if the yield to maturity of the bondchanges. This is not true for bonds with embedded options, especially as thebond price gets close to the strike price. For example, the price of a callablebond is capped at the strike price as the yield levels decl<strong>in</strong>e and the embeddedcall option is <strong>in</strong>-the-money. For this reason, a corporate bond with anembedded call option can be viewed as a portfolio compris<strong>in</strong>g a noncallablebond and a short-call option on the bond. Because the bondholder is shorta call option, the bondholder must receive a premium up front for the calloption sold to the bond issuer. This up-front premium is usually reflectedthrough a lower traded price of the callable bond as opposed to a noncallablebond with similar maturity and cash flows. Hence, callable bondstrade at higher yields than noncallable bonds of the same issuer with similarmaturity. The correspond<strong>in</strong>g yield pickup of the callable bond is referredto as the option-adjusted spread.<strong>Bond</strong>s with embedded options exhibit a price–yield relationship that isdifferent from an option-free or conventional bond. In particular, the differencesare more pronounced as the embedded option gets closer to be<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>-the-money. The distortion <strong>in</strong> the price–yield relationship of bonds withembedded options <strong>in</strong> relation to option-free bonds arises from a phenomenoncalled price compression. Price compression occurs <strong>in</strong> the regionaround the strike price of the option where yield changes have very little<strong>in</strong>fluence on the price of the bond. This suggests that modified durationand convexity may not capture the true risk from yield changes of bondswith embedded options. In order to model the price compression process<strong>in</strong>to the risk measures, one has to take <strong>in</strong>to account the risk characteristicsof the bond’s embedded option. The relevant risk measures for an optionare the so-called delta and gamma of the option, which model first- andsecond-order changes, respectively, to the option price due to a change <strong>in</strong>the price of the bond without the embedded option. Specifically, for acallable bond, if P NC denotes the dirty price of the noncallable part of thebond and P O the price of the embedded call option, then delta and gammaare given, respectively, byanddelta dP OdP NC(4.7)gamma d2 P OdP 2 NC(4.8)


Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong> 55<strong>Risk</strong> measures that take <strong>in</strong>to account the price risk of the embeddedoptions are referred to as option-adjusted risk measures. Thus, the appropriaterisk measures that capture the price risk from yield changes of bondswith embedded options are option-adjusted duration and option-adjustedconvexity. It is also common to refer to these measures as effective durationand effective convexity, respectively. One can show that effective durationand effective convexity for a callable bond are given, respectively, byD eff D P NCP CB (1 delta)C eff P NCP CB[C (1 delta) P NC gamma D 2 ](4.9)(4.10)In these equations, P CB is the dirty price of the callable bond and D and Care the modified duration and convexity of the bond, respectively, withoutthe embedded call option.For putable bonds, where the bondholder is long a put option, the correspond<strong>in</strong>gequations for effective duration and effective convexity aregiven, respectively, byandD eff D P NPP PB (1 delta)C eff P NPP PB[C (1 delta) P NP gamma D 2 ](4.11)(4.12)In equations (4.11) and (4.12), P PB is the dirty price of the putable bond andP NP is the dirty price of the bond without the put option. Note that deltafor a callable bond is positive, whereas for a putable bond delta is negative.One can easily deduce from equations (4.9) to (4.12) that as the embeddedoption becomes worthless, delta and gamma tend to zero and the callableor putable bond trades as a conventional bond. In this case, effective durationand effective convexity are equal to modified duration and convexityof a conventional bond. On the other hand, if the embedded option is <strong>in</strong>the-money,delta is 1 for a callable bond and 1 for a putable bond andgamma is 0 for both. This has the implication that effective duration andeffective convexity are both equal to 0 under this scenario.I mentioned earlier that callable bonds have a yield pickup overcomparable-maturity noncallable bonds. In case the bondholder is long aput option, which is the case for putable bonds, then the bondholder must


56 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSpay a premium up front to acquire this put option. As a result, putablebonds trade at lower yields than conventional bonds of identical maturity.To compare the relative attractiveness of a callable or a putable bond withconventional bonds, the term effective yield is usually used. Effective yieldis the implied yield of the noncallable or nonputable part of the bond.In the rest of this book, I use only the measures effective yield, effectiveduration, and effective convexity to quantify the corporate bond’s yield andprice risk to yield changes. Unless explicitly stated otherwise, I refer to thesemeasures simply as yield, duration, and convexity, respectively, and use theabbreviations y, D, and C, respectively, to denote them.PORTFOLIO AGGREGATESThe discussion so far has focused on quantify<strong>in</strong>g the price risk of a s<strong>in</strong>glecorporate bond <strong>in</strong> response to changes <strong>in</strong> yield. From a portfolio managementperspective, it is more important to estimate the price risk from yieldchanges for an entire corporate bond portfolio. This is done by def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g theaggregate risk measures effective portfolio duration and effective portfolioconvexity, which are simply the weighted averages of effective duration andeffective convexity of the <strong>in</strong>dividual bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio.For purposes of illustration, consider the portfolio to comprise cashhold<strong>in</strong>gs and N corporate bonds. If A c denotes the amount <strong>in</strong> cash and NE ithe nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure to the ith corporate bond hav<strong>in</strong>g a dirty price P dirty,ifor $1 face value, then the market value of the portfolio is given byM P A c aNi1NE i P dirty,i(4.13)If w i denotes the weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio, it is easy to verify thatw i NE i P dirty,iM P(4.14)Similarly, the weight of cash <strong>in</strong> the portfolio is given byw c A cM P(4.15)Follow<strong>in</strong>g standard market convention that a cash position is not subjectto market risk, the duration and convexity of the cash hold<strong>in</strong>gs can be setto zero. Hence, the effective portfolio duration and effective portfolio


Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong> 57convexity are given, respectively, byandD P aNi1C P aNi1w i D iw i C i(4.16)(4.17)Another portfolio aggregate that is often computed is the average effectiveyield of the portfolio. Specifically, if R c denotes the <strong>in</strong>terest rate earnedon cash and y i the effective yield of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio, then theeffective yield of the portfolio is given byy P w c R c aNEffective portfolio duration def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> equation (4.16) has the risk <strong>in</strong>terpretationof represent<strong>in</strong>g the percentage change <strong>in</strong> a portfolio’s marketvalue for a 100-basis po<strong>in</strong>t change <strong>in</strong> effective yield of every bond <strong>in</strong> theportfolio. Includ<strong>in</strong>g the portfolio’s effective convexity improves this pricerisk estimate. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the approximate change <strong>in</strong> market value of aportfolio result<strong>in</strong>g from a change y P to the effective yield of the portfoliois given byi1w i y i¢M P M P D P ¢y P 0.5M P C P ¢y 2 P(4.19)DYNAMICS OF THE YIELD CURVEThe portfolio aggregate risk measures def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the preced<strong>in</strong>g section providean approximate measure of price risk due to yield changes. However, it isimportant to realize that these risk measures are derived under the implicitassumption that the yield of every bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio will change by anidentical amount. Under this assumption, the par yield curve shape change isrestricted to a parallel shift. Note that a par yield curve is the yield curveobta<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>in</strong>terpolat<strong>in</strong>g the effective yield of bonds with different maturities.The extent to which portfolio duration and portfolio convexity capture marketrisk aris<strong>in</strong>g from yield changes depends on the extent to which parallelshifts of the yield curve are representative of yield curve shape changes.To <strong>in</strong>vestigate whether parallel shifts expla<strong>in</strong> a significant proportionof the change <strong>in</strong> shape of the yield curve, one can exam<strong>in</strong>e the proportionof yield curve variability expla<strong>in</strong>ed by parallel shifts us<strong>in</strong>g historical data. If


58 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSchanges to the yield curve are primarily parallel shifts, then yield changesacross different maturities should be perfectly correlated. However, empiricalevidence suggests that yield changes for different maturities are onlystrongly but not perfectly correlated, lead<strong>in</strong>g to the conclusion that parallelshifts do not fully model the dynamics of the yield curve. Of course, the evidencethat yield changes across different maturities are strongly correlatedimplies that yield curve shape changes could be expla<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g relativelyfew factors. One way to identify these factors is to carry out a pr<strong>in</strong>cipalcomponent decomposition of the sample covariance matrix of yieldchanges. This makes it possible to identify those factors that expla<strong>in</strong> a significantproportion of the total variance <strong>in</strong> the sample data. In simple terms,pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component decomposition refers to the process of construct<strong>in</strong>gnew random variables through l<strong>in</strong>ear comb<strong>in</strong>ations of orig<strong>in</strong>al randomvariables with the primary objective of achiev<strong>in</strong>g data reduction. In thepresent case, these random variables correspond to yield changes across differentmaturities of the par yield curve.To illustrate the mathematical concept beh<strong>in</strong>d pr<strong>in</strong>cipal componentdecomposition, consider a random vector x [x 1 , x 2 ,..., x m ] T hav<strong>in</strong>g acovariance matrix with eigenvalues l 1 l 2 l m 0. Now constructnew random variables z 1 , z 2 ,..., z m that are some l<strong>in</strong>ear comb<strong>in</strong>ationsof the random variables x 1 , x 2 ,..., This l<strong>in</strong>ear transformationgenerates the new random variable z i / x m .Ti x, which has a variance given byVar(z i ) / Ti / i(4.20)If one chooses / i to be the normalized eigenvector correspond<strong>in</strong>g to the itheigenvalue, then the variance of the random variable z i (usually referred toas the ith pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component) is equal to the eigenvalue i . The proportionof the total variance of the orig<strong>in</strong>al random variables expla<strong>in</strong>ed by theith pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component is given by l i /(l 1 l m ). To achieve datareduction, one usually chooses the first p pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components that expla<strong>in</strong>a significant proportion of the total variance <strong>in</strong> the orig<strong>in</strong>al data set.The advantage of carry<strong>in</strong>g out a pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysis is that itoften reveals relationships that are not otherwise evident from an exam<strong>in</strong>ationof the orig<strong>in</strong>al data. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a pr<strong>in</strong>cipal decomposition carried outon the historical yield changes for different maturities reveals that three factors,namely shift, twist, and curvature, are sufficient to expla<strong>in</strong> the dynamicsof the yield curve. For purposes of illustration, Exhibit 4.1 shows the proportionof total variance expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the first three pr<strong>in</strong>cipal componentsfor swap curves <strong>in</strong> the U.S. dollar and euro markets. The covariance matrixused <strong>in</strong> the calculation was computed us<strong>in</strong>g times series compris<strong>in</strong>g weeklychanges of quoted swap rates for different maturities over the period July1999 to June 2002.


Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong> 59EXHIBIT 4.1Proportion of Variance Expla<strong>in</strong>ed by Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal ComponentsFactor Type USD Swap Curve (%) EUR Swap Curve (%)Shift (S) 90.8 94.0S twist (T) 98.4 96.6S T curvature 99.2 98.7Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Exhibit 4.1, one can conclude that two pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components,namely level shift and twist (flatten<strong>in</strong>g or steepen<strong>in</strong>g of the yieldcurve), sufficiently expla<strong>in</strong> a significant proportion of the historical changesto the yield curve. Based on this evidence, I use only two factors for model<strong>in</strong>gthe yield curve risk.In general, it is not necessary for the two risk factors to be the fundamentaldirection vectors obta<strong>in</strong>ed through pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component decomposition.In practice, it is only important to choose two fundamental directionvectors that are easy to <strong>in</strong>terpret and expla<strong>in</strong> a significant proportion of thetotal variance of the orig<strong>in</strong>al variables. The choice of the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal componentvectors is primarily motivated by the fact that these are optimal directionvectors for the sample period over which they are computed. Outsidethis sample period, however, these direction vectors may not be optimal<strong>in</strong> the sense of be<strong>in</strong>g able to model the maximum variance for the numberof risk factors chosen. For these reasons, I choose risk factors that are identicalacross different markets but nonetheless model a significant proportionof the variance. In particular, the market risk model presented <strong>in</strong> the nextsection uses a 10-basis po<strong>in</strong>t parallel shift and a 10-basis po<strong>in</strong>t flatten<strong>in</strong>gof the par yield curve as the two risk factors to model yield curve risk.Exhibit 4.2 shows the two risk factors used to model the yield curve risk.EXHIBIT 4.2Shift and Twist <strong>Risk</strong> FactorsShift <strong>in</strong> par yields (bps)6420-2-4-6-8-10-120 5 10 15 20 25 30Time to maturity (years)


60 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSNote that the twist risk factor is modeled to be flat over the maturity ranges0 to 1 year and 5 to 6 years.To <strong>in</strong>vestigate whether the chosen shift and twist risk factors expla<strong>in</strong> asignificant proportion of the total variance, I aga<strong>in</strong> use the same (weekly)data set (of swap rate changes over the period July 1999 to June 2002) andcompare this with the figures <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 4.1. In comput<strong>in</strong>g the proportionof total variance modeled by these two risk factors, one needs to accountfor the fact that the twist risk factor may not be orthogonal to the shift riskfactor (<strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that these two risk factors may be correlated). If the varianceof the shift and twist risk factors is denoted 2 s and 2 t , respectively,then the variance expla<strong>in</strong>ed by these factors (under the assumption that thecorrelation between them is ) is given by 2 expla<strong>in</strong>ed 2 s (1 ) 2 tl 1 l 2 l m(4.21)Note that the <strong>in</strong>dividual factor variances can be computed us<strong>in</strong>g equation(4.20) where the normalized vector i is chosen to correspond to therisk factor be<strong>in</strong>g modeled. The correlation between the risk factors isgiven by / Ts / t s t(4.22)where s and t denote the normalized shift risk vector and twist risk vector,respectively. The results obta<strong>in</strong>ed by carry<strong>in</strong>g out this analysis are shown <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 4.3.Compar<strong>in</strong>g Exhibits 4.1 and 4.3, one can <strong>in</strong>fer that the chosen shift andtwist risk factors jo<strong>in</strong>tly expla<strong>in</strong> more than 95 percent of the variance forthe U.S. dollar swap curve. The proportion of variance expla<strong>in</strong>ed for theeuro swap curve is slightly less than this value. The empirical evidencereported here provides a strong motivation for us<strong>in</strong>g these two risk factorsto model the yield curve dynamics. Additionally, the direction vectors theyrepresent are generic for any yield curve and are therefore easier to <strong>in</strong>terpretthan pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components.EXHIBIT 4.3Proportion of Variance Expla<strong>in</strong>ed by Chosen <strong>Risk</strong> FactorsFactor Type USD Swap Curve (%) EUR Swap Curve (%)Shift 90.0 82.7Shift twist 95.6 92.3


Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong> 61OTHER SOURCES OF MARKET RISK<strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> credit risk is usually the primary focus of corporate bond portfoliomanagers. For this reason, identify<strong>in</strong>g corporate borrowers with either astable credit rat<strong>in</strong>g or the potential to improve their credit rat<strong>in</strong>g is the majorpreoccupation of portfolio managers. However, some corporate borrowerswho meet these criteria may issue bonds <strong>in</strong> a currency that is different fromthe corporate bond portfolio’s base currency. As a result, it is quite possiblethat a particular corporate bond the portfolio manager wishes to buy isissued <strong>in</strong> a currency different from the portfolio’s base currency. In this case,the portfolio manager has to hedge the exchange rate risk aris<strong>in</strong>g from thepurchase of a bond denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> a foreign currency. The exchange raterisk is usually hedged through the purchase of currency forwards.In general, the guidel<strong>in</strong>es for manag<strong>in</strong>g the corporate bond portfoliospecify whether exchange rate risk is permitted. In most cases, only a smallpercentage of foreign currency risk is permitted to ensure that, from anoperational po<strong>in</strong>t of view, frequent currency rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g is not necessary. Inorder to identify both <strong>in</strong>tentional and un<strong>in</strong>tentional market risk exposuresaris<strong>in</strong>g from exchange rate risk, one has to <strong>in</strong>clude exchange rate risk <strong>in</strong> themarket risk calculation.Another source of market risk arises from changes <strong>in</strong> implied yieldvolatility, which <strong>in</strong> turn has an impact on the prices of callable and putablebonds. In the next section, I develop a market risk model that takes <strong>in</strong>toaccount yield curve risk, exchange rate risk, and implied yield volatility riskfor manag<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond portfolio.MARKET RISK MODELIn this section, I focus on develop<strong>in</strong>g a market risk model to measure theportfolio’s market risk exposure relative to the benchmark. Consider<strong>in</strong>gthat a risk model’s key function is to identify sources of mismatch betweenportfolio and benchmark returns, the first step is to select a set of risk factorsthat drive security returns. For a corporate bond portfolio, an obviouschoice for the market risk factors would be yield curve shape changes <strong>in</strong>all markets relevant to the portfolio and the benchmark. I <strong>in</strong>dicated earlierthat two risk factors are generally sufficient to expla<strong>in</strong> a significant proportionof the yield curve shape changes. The component of risk modeled bythese two factors is usually referred to as the systematic risk. In develop<strong>in</strong>gthe market risk model, I restrict attention to model<strong>in</strong>g only systematicrisk and work with weekly time series data. Issuer-specific risk aris<strong>in</strong>gfrom hold<strong>in</strong>g specific corporate names <strong>in</strong> the portfolio is modeled undercredit risk.


62 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSCommon to any market risk model is the underly<strong>in</strong>g assumption that historicalrisk factor realizations serve as good approximations for characteriz<strong>in</strong>gthe distribution of risk factors <strong>in</strong> the future. Under this assumption, the covariancematrix computed us<strong>in</strong>g historical volatilities and correlations of relevantmarket risk factors serves as a suitable risk model. I <strong>in</strong>dicate <strong>in</strong> this section howto construct such a market risk model. Hav<strong>in</strong>g argued that two risk factors aresufficient to model the changes to the swap curve, I first illustrate how the shiftand twist risk factors for any given yield curve can be estimated.Denote the par yields by y k i (t) at time t, where i refers to the maturityand k refers to the specific yield curve under consideration. For the sake ofconsistency, assume that for every yield curve the <strong>in</strong>dex i runs from 1 to n.The time series of weekly yield changes for the ith maturity po<strong>in</strong>t on theyield curve for the kth yield curve is given by¢y k i (t) y k i (t) y k i (t 1), i 1,...,n(4.23)The earlier analysis <strong>in</strong>dicated that these yield changes can be modeled us<strong>in</strong>ga shift component and a twist component. For <strong>in</strong>stance, if one denotes s10 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts as the shift component across all maturities and t i asthe twist component for the ith maturity for a 10-basis po<strong>in</strong>t flatten<strong>in</strong>g ofthe yield curve shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 4.2, then the yield changes (assumed to be<strong>in</strong> basis po<strong>in</strong>ts) can be represented as¢y k i (t) a k t ¢s b k t ¢t i e k i , i 1,...,n(4.24)In equation (4.24), a k t and b k t are coefficients associated with shift andtwist risk factors, respectively, that model weekly yield changes. To determ<strong>in</strong>ethese coefficients, one needs to m<strong>in</strong>imize the sum of the squared residualse k i for i 1,...,n. One can show <strong>in</strong> this case that a k t and b k t aregiven, respectively, bya k t a ani1nn n¢t 2 i a ¢y k i a ¢t i a ¢t i ¢y k i bi1i1 i1nn 2a n a ¢t 2 i a a ¢t i b b ¢si1i1(4.25)andb k t a n ani1a n an¢t i ¢y k i ani1i1¢t 2 i a ann¢t i ai1i1¢t i b¢y k i b2b(4.26)


Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong> 63The next task is to identify the relevant yield curves to be used to modelmarket risk for a corporate bond portfolio. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that the <strong>in</strong>tentionis to model only market risk aris<strong>in</strong>g from systematic risk factors, the appropriateyield curves are the swap curves <strong>in</strong> different currency markets. Onecan justify such a choice on the basis of the strong correlation corporatebond yield changes have with changes <strong>in</strong> swap rates. Assum<strong>in</strong>g the corporatebond portfolio is restricted to comprise only bonds issued <strong>in</strong> either U.S.dollars or euros, the yield curves to be considered for model<strong>in</strong>g market riskare the swap curves <strong>in</strong> U.S. dollar and euro markets.When the portfolio or benchmark returns are also dependent onexchange rate movements, the market risk model has to <strong>in</strong>clude factors thatcapture this risk component. Aga<strong>in</strong>, if one restricts the permissibleexchange rate risk to U.S. dollars aga<strong>in</strong>st euros, one additional risk factoris required to capture this component of market risk. In order to model therisk exposure to changes <strong>in</strong> the exchange rate, assume that this risk factormodels a 1 percent appreciation of the foreign currency aga<strong>in</strong>st the basecurrency of the portfolio. In this case, the coefficient c t associated with thechosen risk factor us<strong>in</strong>g weekly exchange rate data is given byc t 100 x t x t1x t1(4.27)In equation (4.27), x t denotes the exchange rate of the foreign currency attime t expressed <strong>in</strong> units of foreign currency required to buy one unit of theportfolio’s base currency.F<strong>in</strong>ally, to model the market risk result<strong>in</strong>g from changes <strong>in</strong> impliedyield volatility, one <strong>in</strong>cludes the implied yield volatility risk factor. This riskfactor is <strong>in</strong>tended to capture the price risk aris<strong>in</strong>g from changes <strong>in</strong> theimplied yield volatility when callable or putable bonds are held <strong>in</strong> the portfolioor benchmark. If one assumes the implied yield volatility risk factormodels a 1 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> implied yield volatility, then the coefficient v tassociated with implied yield volatility risk factor is given byv t 100 t t1 t(4.28)In equation (4.28), t refers to the implied yield volatility for some suitableoption contract at time t (a 1-month swaption on the 5-year swap rate isused <strong>in</strong> this risk model). Aga<strong>in</strong> assume that the implied yield volatility timeseries is constructed us<strong>in</strong>g weekly data.One can now construct the risk model for comput<strong>in</strong>g the exposure ofthe portfolio relative to the benchmark to various market risk factors. Therelevant risk factors comprise the shift and twist risk factors for the U.S.


64 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 4.4Market <strong>Risk</strong> ModelUSD Shift USD Twist EUR Shift EUR Twist FX Factor Yield VolUSD shift 1.110 0.251 0.518 0.051 0.158 0.128USD twist 0.251 1.051 0.044 0.318 0.004 0.107EUR shift 0.518 0.044 0.467 0.019 0.062 0.096EUR twist 0.051 0.318 0.019 0.727 0.032 0.191FX factor 0.158 0.004 0.062 0.032 0.918 0.319Yield vol. 0.128 0.107 0.096 0.191 0.319 11.528dollar and euro swap curves, the exchange rate risk factor and theimplied yield volatility factor. In this case, one can construct the vectortime series of the risk factor coefficients us<strong>in</strong>g weekly data, denoted5 (t)6 5[a usdt b usdt a eurt b eurt c t v t ]6. The risk model for measur<strong>in</strong>g exposures tosystematic risk factors turns out to be simply the covariance matrix [ ij ],where ij denotes the covariance between the ith and jth time series components<strong>in</strong> (t). Exhibit 4.4 shows the six-factor market risk model estimatedus<strong>in</strong>g weekly data over the period 31 March 1999 to 3 April 2001.Given the risk model (or equivalently the risk factor covariancematrix), one can compute the track<strong>in</strong>g error of the portfolio versus thebenchmark aris<strong>in</strong>g from mismatches <strong>in</strong> the exposures to market risk factors.As a prerequisite for this, one has to compute the sensitivities to variousmarket risk factors that have been modeled.To <strong>in</strong>dicate the computation of the sensitivities to market risk factors,first assume that the market value of the portfolio is given by M P . Now considera shift of s 10 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts to the U.S. dollar swap curve. Underthe assumption that the U.S. dollar swap curve dynamics capture the systematicrisk of corporate bonds denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> U.S. dollars, the yields ofall U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated bonds change by 10 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. Under thisscenario, the market value of the portfolio is different if corporate bondsdenom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> U.S. dollars are held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. Generically denot<strong>in</strong>gthis risk factor as k, the sensitivity to the kth risk factor <strong>in</strong> basis po<strong>in</strong>ts isgiven byS k P 10,000 Mk P M PM P(4.29)In equation (4.29), M k P is the new market value of the portfolio under therisk scenario. One can similarly compute the sensitivity <strong>in</strong> basis po<strong>in</strong>ts tothe kth risk factor for the benchmark, which is given asS k B 10,000 Mk B M BM B(4.30)


Model<strong>in</strong>g Market <strong>Risk</strong> 65Note that for estimat<strong>in</strong>g sensitivity to exchange rate risk, one has toshock the relevant foreign currency to appreciate by 1 percent aga<strong>in</strong>st thebase currency of the portfolio. Similarly, to estimate the sensitivity tochanges <strong>in</strong> implied yield volatility, one has to shock the implied yieldvolatilites of all callable and putable bonds to <strong>in</strong>crease by 1 percent andthen revalue the portfolio and benchmark under this scenario.For the chosen risk model, let S and S PB denote the vectors of factorload<strong>in</strong>gs (or sensitivity) <strong>in</strong> basis po<strong>in</strong>ts for the portfolio and benchmark,respectively. The annualized ex ante track<strong>in</strong>g error of the portfoliodenoted <strong>in</strong> basis po<strong>in</strong>ts aris<strong>in</strong>g from exposures to market risk factors isgiven byT e 252(S P S B) T ©(S P S B)(4.31)The scal<strong>in</strong>g factor of 52 <strong>in</strong> equation (4.31) is required to annualize thetrack<strong>in</strong>g error computed us<strong>in</strong>g weekly time series data.The annualized volatility of the portfolio <strong>in</strong> basis po<strong>in</strong>ts can be determ<strong>in</strong>edfrom the follow<strong>in</strong>g equation: P 252 S TP ©S P(4.32)The risk factor sensitivities <strong>in</strong>troduced here are useful <strong>in</strong> the context offormulat<strong>in</strong>g an optimization problem to f<strong>in</strong>d portfolios that replicate therisk factors of a given corporate bond benchmark. This is discussed <strong>in</strong>Chapter 10.QUESTIONS1. The dirty price of a bond matur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 4.25 years with a 5 percentcoupon rate paid on a semiannual basis is $102.50. Compute the yieldto maturity, modified duration, and convexity of the bond. Us<strong>in</strong>g modifiedduration and convexity, f<strong>in</strong>d the approximate price change for a25-basis po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> yield.2. A portfolio manager holds two bonds <strong>in</strong> his portfolio, both pay<strong>in</strong>g semiannualcoupons. The nom<strong>in</strong>al amount <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> bond A is $1 millionand this bond is trad<strong>in</strong>g at a dirty price of $101.50. <strong>Bond</strong> A matures <strong>in</strong>2.25 years and has a coupon rate of 4.5 percent. The nom<strong>in</strong>al amount<strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> bond B is $2.5 million and bond B is trad<strong>in</strong>g at a dirty priceof $105.25. <strong>Bond</strong> B matures <strong>in</strong> 8.75 years and has a coupon rate of 5percent. Compute the yield to maturity, modified duration, and convexityof the bond portfolio. If the portfolio manager’s performance is measured


66 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSaga<strong>in</strong>st a 1- to 5-year sector benchmark hav<strong>in</strong>g a modified duration of2.25 years, what is the view of the portfolio manager?3. Expla<strong>in</strong> the motivation for do<strong>in</strong>g a pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component decompositionof the yield curve.4. A portfolio manager prefers to use two risk factors to model the yieldcurve dynamics but would like one factor to be the duration (imply<strong>in</strong>ga parallel shift of yield curve as one factor). Expla<strong>in</strong> what criterion youwould use to identify the second risk factor to ensure that the two factorsexpla<strong>in</strong> a large proportion of the variance <strong>in</strong> the yield curve.5. What is the track<strong>in</strong>g error of a portfolio? A portfolio has a monthlytrack<strong>in</strong>g error of 25 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. What is its annualized track<strong>in</strong>g error?6. For the two-bond portfolio given <strong>in</strong> Question 2, f<strong>in</strong>d the shift risk andtwist risk sensitivities <strong>in</strong> basis po<strong>in</strong>ts for the portfolio us<strong>in</strong>g the risk factorsgiven <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 4.2.


CHAPTER 5Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong><strong>Credit</strong> risk constitutes the dom<strong>in</strong>ant part of the risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate bondportfolio. As a consequence, the ability to model credit risk accuratelyplays an important role <strong>in</strong> decid<strong>in</strong>g whether the risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate bondportfolio can be managed effectively. However, model<strong>in</strong>g credit risk is amuch more difficult task than model<strong>in</strong>g market risk. Most of the difficultiesrelate to the differences <strong>in</strong> the conceptual approaches used for model<strong>in</strong>gcredit risk and data limitations associated with parameter specification andestimation. Hence, there is <strong>in</strong>variably a subjective element to the model<strong>in</strong>gof credit risk and, as such, credit risk model<strong>in</strong>g is a mixture of art andscience. This subjective element is much more evident when one aggregatescredit risk at the portfolio level, which is discussed <strong>in</strong> the next chapter. Inthis chapter, I discuss various factors that are important determ<strong>in</strong>ants ofcredit risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond and <strong>in</strong>dicate the methods used to estimatethese at the security level. Subsequently, I <strong>in</strong>troduce standard risk measuresthat are used to quantify credit risk.ELEMENTS OF CREDIT RISK<strong>Credit</strong> risk, <strong>in</strong> broad terms, refers to the risk of a loss aris<strong>in</strong>g from the obligoror issuer not be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a position to service the debt obligations. Also attributedto credit risk is the mark-to-market loss of a bond result<strong>in</strong>g from achange <strong>in</strong> the market perception of the issuer’s ability to service the debt <strong>in</strong> thefuture. In most cases, this change <strong>in</strong> the market perception will be either precededor succeeded by a change <strong>in</strong> the credit quality of the issuer. In comput<strong>in</strong>gcredit risk at the security level, the follow<strong>in</strong>g factors play important roles:Probability of default. This is the probability that the issuer will defaulton its contractual obligations to repay its debt. Because probability ofdefault (PD) is a function of the time horizon over which one measuresthe debt-servic<strong>in</strong>g ability, it is standard practice to assume a 1-yearhorizon to quantify this.67


68 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSRecovery rate. This is the extent to which the face value of an obligationcan be recovered once the counterparty has defaulted. The recoveryrate (RR) is usually taken to be the price at which the security trades<strong>in</strong> the secondary market immediately after the issuer has defaulted oncontractual payments. Among other variables, seniority of the bondand the prevail<strong>in</strong>g economic environment are important determ<strong>in</strong>antsof recovery rates.Rat<strong>in</strong>g migration. Short of default, this is the extent to which the creditquality of the issuer improves or deteriorates as expressed by a change<strong>in</strong> the probability of default. This affects the relative spread versus therisk-free yield curve at which the corporate bond trades.In the follow<strong>in</strong>g sections, I discuss each of these factors <strong>in</strong> greater detail,and, wherever relevant, <strong>in</strong>dicate methods commonly employed to estimatethe quantities of <strong>in</strong>terest.Probability of DefaultThe key determ<strong>in</strong>ant of the credit risk of an issuer is the uncerta<strong>in</strong>tyregard<strong>in</strong>g the issuer’s ability to service debt obligations as expressedthrough the default probability. In general, the approaches used to determ<strong>in</strong>edefault probabilities at the issuer level fall <strong>in</strong>to two broad categories.The first is empirical <strong>in</strong> nature and requires the existence of apublic credit-quality rat<strong>in</strong>g scheme. The second is based on Merton’soptions theory framework and is therefore a structural approach. Theempirical approach to estimat<strong>in</strong>g the default probability makes use of ahistorical database of corporate defaults to form a static pool of companieshav<strong>in</strong>g a particular credit rat<strong>in</strong>g for a given year. Annual defaultrates are then calculated for each static pool, which are then aggregatedto provide an estimate of the average historical default probability for agiven credit rat<strong>in</strong>g. If one uses this approach, then the default probabilitiesfor any two issuers hav<strong>in</strong>g the same credit rat<strong>in</strong>g will be identical.On the other hand, the option pric<strong>in</strong>g approach to estimat<strong>in</strong>g defaultprobability uses current estimates of the firm’s assets, liabilities, and assetvolatility and hence is related to the dynamics of the underly<strong>in</strong>g structureof the firm. I discuss each of these approaches <strong>in</strong> greater detail <strong>in</strong> whatfollows.Empirical Approach Many major rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Moody’sInvestors Service, Standard & Poor’s Corporation, and Fitch Rat<strong>in</strong>gs determ<strong>in</strong>ethe probability of default us<strong>in</strong>g the empirical approach. Rat<strong>in</strong>g agenciesassign credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs to different issuers based on extensive analysis ofboth the quantitative and the qualitative performance of a firm. This analysis


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 69is <strong>in</strong>tended to capture the level of credit risk (how credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs are assignedis beyond the scope of this book). For the purpose of illustrat<strong>in</strong>g the empiricalapproach used to determ<strong>in</strong>e default probabilities for different credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs,I discuss Moody’s methodology.Moody’s rat<strong>in</strong>g symbols for issuer rat<strong>in</strong>gs reflect op<strong>in</strong>ions on the issuer’sability to honor senior unsecured f<strong>in</strong>ancial obligations and contracts denom<strong>in</strong>ated<strong>in</strong> foreign and/or domestic currency. The rat<strong>in</strong>g gradations providebondholders with a simple system to measure an issuer’s ability to meet itssenior f<strong>in</strong>ancial obligations. Exhibit 5.1 shows the various rat<strong>in</strong>g symbolsassigned by Moody’s with a short description of the rat<strong>in</strong>g implication.EXHIBIT 5.1<strong>Credit</strong> Quality Implication for Moody’s Rat<strong>in</strong>g SymbolsRat<strong>in</strong>g SymbolAaaAaABaaBaBCaaCaCRat<strong>in</strong>g ImplicationIssuers rated Aaa offer exceptional f<strong>in</strong>ancial security, althoughthe credit-worth<strong>in</strong>ess of these entities is likely to change, suchchanges most unlikely may not impair their fundamentallystrong positionIssuers rated Aa offer excellent f<strong>in</strong>ancial security; compared toAaa issuers, long-term risks of Aa issuers are somewhat greaterIssuers rated A offer good f<strong>in</strong>ancial security; however, elementsmay be present that suggest a susceptibility to impairment <strong>in</strong>the futureIssuers rated Baa offer adequate f<strong>in</strong>ancial security; however,certa<strong>in</strong> protective elements may be lack<strong>in</strong>g or may beunreliable over any great period of timeIssuers rated Ba offer questionable f<strong>in</strong>ancial security; often theability of these issuers to meet obligations may be moderateand not well safeguarded <strong>in</strong> the futureIssuers rated B offer poor f<strong>in</strong>ancial security; assurance ofpayment of obligations over any long period of time is smallIssuers rated Caa offer very poor f<strong>in</strong>ancial security; they maybe <strong>in</strong> default on their obligations or there may be presentelements of danger with respect to payment of obligations onscheduleIssuers rated Ca offer extremely poor f<strong>in</strong>ancial security; suchissuers are often <strong>in</strong> default on their obligations or have othermarked shortcom<strong>in</strong>gsIssuers rated C are the lowest rated class of entity and areusually <strong>in</strong> default on their obligations, and potential recoveryvalues are lowSource: “Rat<strong>in</strong>g Def<strong>in</strong>itions,” Moody’s Investors Service. © Moody’s InvestorsService, Inc., and/or its affiliates. Repr<strong>in</strong>ted with permission. All rights reserved.


70 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSIn addition to the these generic rat<strong>in</strong>g categories, Moody’s appliesnumerical modifiers 1, 2, and 3 to the rat<strong>in</strong>g categories from Aa to Caa. Themodifier 1 <strong>in</strong>dicates that the issuer is <strong>in</strong> the higher end of its letter-rat<strong>in</strong>gcategory, the modifier 2 <strong>in</strong>dicates a mid-range rank<strong>in</strong>g, and the modifier 3<strong>in</strong>dicates that the issuer is <strong>in</strong> the lower end of the letter-rat<strong>in</strong>g category. It iscustomary to refer to a rat<strong>in</strong>g change from grade Aa1 to Aa2 as a one-notchrat<strong>in</strong>g downgrade. <strong>Bond</strong>s issued by firms rated between Aaa to Baa arereferred to as <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade bonds; the rest are referred to as non<strong>in</strong>vestment-gradebonds.It is important to emphasize here that Moody’s rat<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong>corporateassessments of both the likelihood and the severity of default. Consider<strong>in</strong>gthat a particular issuer could have debt issues with different collateral andseniority, Moody’s approach leads to different rat<strong>in</strong>gs for a particularissuer’s different debt issues. However, when an issuer is deemed to havedefaulted on a particular debt issue, cross-default clauses require all outstand<strong>in</strong>gdebt of the issuer to be considered as hav<strong>in</strong>g defaulted. This <strong>in</strong>turn leads to the follow<strong>in</strong>g question: What events signal the default of anissuer? Moody’s def<strong>in</strong>ition of default considers three types of default events:1. There is a missed or delayed disbursement of <strong>in</strong>terest and/or pr<strong>in</strong>cipal<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g delayed payments made with<strong>in</strong> a grace period.2. An issuer files for bankruptcy or legal receivership occurs.3. A distressed exchange occurs where: (1) the issuer offers bondholders anew security or package of securities that amounts to a dim<strong>in</strong>ishedf<strong>in</strong>ancial obligation or (2) the exchange has the apparent purpose ofhelp<strong>in</strong>g the borrower default.These def<strong>in</strong>itions of default are meant to capture events that change therelationship between the bondholder and the bond issuer <strong>in</strong> such a way asto subject the bondholder to an economic loss.The empirical approach relies on historical defaults of various ratedissuers. This requires form<strong>in</strong>g a static pool of issuers with a given rat<strong>in</strong>gevery year and comput<strong>in</strong>g the ratio of defaulted issuers after a 1-year periodto the number of issuers that could have potentially defaulted for thegiven rat<strong>in</strong>g. If, dur<strong>in</strong>g the year, rat<strong>in</strong>gs for certa<strong>in</strong> issuers are withdrawn,then these issuers are subtracted from the potential number of issuers whocould have defaulted <strong>in</strong> the static pool. Specifically, the 1-year default ratesfor A-rated issuers dur<strong>in</strong>g a given year represent the number of A-ratedissuers that defaulted over the year divided by the number of A-ratedissuers that could have defaulted over that year. Annual default rates calculated<strong>in</strong> this manner for each rat<strong>in</strong>g grade are then aggregated to providean estimate of the average historical default probability for a given rat<strong>in</strong>ggrade.


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 71I mentioned that although different debt issues of a particular issuercould have different rat<strong>in</strong>gs assigned depend<strong>in</strong>g on the seniority of the issue,cross-default clauses require all outstand<strong>in</strong>g debt of a particular issuer todefault at the same time. This raises an important question when manag<strong>in</strong>gcorporate bond portfolios, namely, whether the issuer rat<strong>in</strong>g or the rat<strong>in</strong>gof the bond issue is to be considered when <strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>g the probability ofdefault. The short answer to this question is that it depends on how creditrisk will be quantified for the given bond. The approach taken here to quantifybond-level credit risk requires that the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the bond issueris the one to be used. This will be evident when I discuss the quantificationof credit risk at the bond level.Merton’s Approach Merton’s approach to estimat<strong>in</strong>g the probability ofdefault of a firm builds on the limited liability rule, which allows shareholdersto default on their obligations while surrender<strong>in</strong>g the firm’s assetsto its creditors. In this framework, the firm’s liabilities are viewed as cont<strong>in</strong>gentclaims on the assets of the firm and default occurs at debt maturitywhen the firm’s asset value falls below the debt value. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that thefirm is f<strong>in</strong>anced by means of equity S t and a s<strong>in</strong>gle zero-coupon debt matur<strong>in</strong>gat time T with face value F and current market value B t , one can representthe firm’s assets at time t asA t S t B t (5.1)The probability of default <strong>in</strong> Merton’s framework for the firm is the probabilitythat the firm’s assets are less than the face value of the debt, whichis given byPD prob[A T F] (5.2)To determ<strong>in</strong>e the probability of default <strong>in</strong> Merton’s framework, one needsto select a suitable model for the process followed by A t . A standard assumptionis to postulate that A t follows a log-normal process with growth rate and asset return volatility A , as follows:A t A 0 exp[A 0.5 2 ABt A 2t z t ](5.3)In equation (5.3), z t is a normally distributed random variable with zeromean and unit variance. Us<strong>in</strong>g equation (5.3) <strong>in</strong> conjunction with equation(5.2), one can denote the probability of default asPD prob[lnA 0 A 0.5 2 ABT A 2T z T lnF](5.4)


72 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSIn equation (5.4), one takes the logarithm on both sides of the <strong>in</strong>equalitybecause do<strong>in</strong>g so does not change the probabilities. Rearrang<strong>in</strong>g theterms <strong>in</strong> equation (5.4), one can represent the probability of default forthe firm asPD prob c z T ln(A 0 F) A 0.5 2 ABTd A 2T(5.5)Because z T is a normally distributed random variable, the probability ofdefault can be represented aswherePD N(D) (5.6)D ln(A 0F) A 0.5 2 ABT A 2TDN(D) 1 exp(0.5x 2 )dx22pq(5.7)(5.8)In equation (5.7), D represents the distance to default, which is the distancebetween the logarithm of the expected asset value at maturity and the logarithmof the default po<strong>in</strong>t normalized by the asset volatility.Although Merton’s framework for determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the probability ofdefault for issuers is rather simple, apply<strong>in</strong>g this directly <strong>in</strong> practice runs<strong>in</strong>to difficulties. This is because firms seldom issue zero-coupon bonds andusually have multiple liabilities. Furthermore, firms <strong>in</strong> distress may be ableto draw on l<strong>in</strong>es of credit to honor coupon and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments, result<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> a maturity transformation of their liabilities.To resolve these difficulties, the KMV Corporation suggested somemodifications to Merton’s framework to make the default probability estimatemean<strong>in</strong>gful <strong>in</strong> a practical sett<strong>in</strong>g 1 (KMV refers to the probability ofdefault as the expected default frequency, or EDF). For <strong>in</strong>stance, rather thanus<strong>in</strong>g the face value of the debt to denote the default po<strong>in</strong>t, KMV suggestsus<strong>in</strong>g the sum of the short-term liabilities (coupon and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal paymentsdue <strong>in</strong> less than 1 year) and one half of the long-term liabilities. This choiceis based on the empirical evidence that firms default when their asset valuereaches a level between the value of total liabilities and the value of short-termliabilities. Furthermore, because the asset returns of the firms may <strong>in</strong> practice


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 73deviate from a normal distribution, KMV maps the distance to default variableD to a historical default statistics database to estimate the probabilityof default. In the KMV framework, default probabilities for issuers can takevalues <strong>in</strong> the range between 0.02 and 20 percent.To illustrate the KMV approach, let DPT denote the default po<strong>in</strong>t andE(A T ) the expected value of the firm’s assets 1 year from now. Then the distanceto default is given byD ln[E(A T)DPT] A 2T ln(A 0DPT) A 0.5 2 ABT A 2T(5.9)In equation (5.9), the market value of the firm’s assets is not observedbecause the liabilities of the firm are not traded. What can be observed <strong>in</strong>the market is the equity value of the firm because equity is traded. Becausethe value of the firm’s equity at time T can be seen as the value of a calloption on the assets of the firm with a strike price equal to the book valueof the liabilities, one has the follow<strong>in</strong>g equation:S T A T N(d 1 ) e rT DPT N(d 2 )(5.10)In equation (5.10), N() is the cumulative standard unit normal distribution,r is the risk-free <strong>in</strong>terest rate, and the variables d 1 and d 2 are given,respectively, byandd 1 ln(A T DPT) Ar 0.5 2 ABT A 2Td 2 d 1 A 2T(5.11)(5.12)It is possible to show that equity return and asset return volatility are relatedthrough the follow<strong>in</strong>g relation: S A TS T N(d 1 ) A(5.13)From this relation, it is possible, us<strong>in</strong>g an iterative procedure, to solve forthe asset value and asset return volatility given the equity value and equityreturn volatility. Know<strong>in</strong>g the asset return volatility and asset value, one cancompute the distance to default us<strong>in</strong>g equation (5.9), from which probabilityof default can be <strong>in</strong>ferred.


74 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSRelative Merits The empirical and structural approaches to determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gissuers’ probability of default can produce significant differences. Bothapproaches have their relative advantages and disadvantages. For <strong>in</strong>stance,the empirical approach has the implicit assumption that all issuers hav<strong>in</strong>gthe same credit rat<strong>in</strong>g will have an identical PD. Furthermore, this defaultprobability is equal to the historical average rate of default. Use of thestructural approach, on the other hand, results <strong>in</strong> PD be<strong>in</strong>g more responsiveto changes <strong>in</strong> economic conditions and bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycles because it<strong>in</strong>corporates current estimates of the asset value and asset return volatilityof the firm <strong>in</strong> deriv<strong>in</strong>g this <strong>in</strong>formation. One drawback, however, is thatthe historical database of defaulted firms comprises mostly <strong>in</strong>dustrial corporates.As a consequence, use of an <strong>in</strong>dustrial corporate default databaseto <strong>in</strong>fer the PD of regulated f<strong>in</strong>ancial firms could potentially result <strong>in</strong>biased PD estimates. Seen from a trad<strong>in</strong>g perspective, credit spreads forcorporates tend to be <strong>in</strong>fluenced much more by agency rat<strong>in</strong>gs and creditrat<strong>in</strong>g downgrades than by EDF values. This has the consequence thatbond market participants tend to attach greater significance to rat<strong>in</strong>gagency decisions for pric<strong>in</strong>g. For the purpose of model<strong>in</strong>g portfolio creditrisk and select<strong>in</strong>g an optimal corporate bond portfolio to replicate thebenchmark risk characteristics, I demonstrate the usefulness of bothapproaches <strong>in</strong> the chapters to follow.On Rat<strong>in</strong>g Outlooks Rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies provide forward-look<strong>in</strong>g assessments ofthe issuers’ creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess over the medium term. Such forward-look<strong>in</strong>gcredit assessments are referred to as rat<strong>in</strong>g outlooks. Outlooks assess thepotential direction of an issuer’s rat<strong>in</strong>g change over the next 6 months to 2years. A positive outlook suggests an improvement <strong>in</strong> credit rat<strong>in</strong>g, a negativeoutlook <strong>in</strong>dicates deterioration <strong>in</strong> credit rat<strong>in</strong>g, and a stable outlooksuggests a rat<strong>in</strong>g change is less likely to occur. <strong>Bond</strong> prices tend to react tochanges <strong>in</strong> rat<strong>in</strong>g outlook although no actual change <strong>in</strong> credit rat<strong>in</strong>g hasoccurred. In particular, the impact on prices is much more significant if theissuer is Baa because a rat<strong>in</strong>g downgrade can result <strong>in</strong> the issuer be<strong>in</strong>g ratednon-<strong>in</strong>vestment grade. Furthermore, if a particular sector (such as telecom)has a negative rat<strong>in</strong>g outlook, a change <strong>in</strong> rat<strong>in</strong>g outlook from stable tonegative for an issuer <strong>in</strong> this sector can also have a significant effect on bondprices.These observations raise the follow<strong>in</strong>g important question: Should anegative or a positive rat<strong>in</strong>g outlook for a given issuer be <strong>in</strong>corporated <strong>in</strong>assess<strong>in</strong>g PD through a downgrade or an upgrade before it has actuallyhappened? The short answer to this question is no, primarily because estimat<strong>in</strong>gcredit risk <strong>in</strong>corporates the probability that the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g ofissuers can change over time. Forc<strong>in</strong>g a rat<strong>in</strong>g change for the issuer beforeit has actually happened may tend to bias the estimate of credit risk.


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 75Captive F<strong>in</strong>ance Companies Large companies <strong>in</strong> most <strong>in</strong>dustrial sectors havecaptive f<strong>in</strong>ance subsidiaries. The pr<strong>in</strong>cipal function of any f<strong>in</strong>ancial subsidiaryis to support the sales of the parent’s products. This function canmake the f<strong>in</strong>ance company a critical component of the parent’s long-termbus<strong>in</strong>ess strategy. In light of this close relationship between the captivef<strong>in</strong>ance company and its parent, credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs for both are usually identical.However, if the legal clauses guarantee that the parent company’s bankruptcydoes not automatically trigger the bankruptcy of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial subsidiary,rat<strong>in</strong>g differences may exist between the parent company and itsf<strong>in</strong>ancial subsidiary. 2 For the purpose of quantify<strong>in</strong>g credit risk, I use theactual credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial subsidiary <strong>in</strong> the calculations.Estimat<strong>in</strong>g the probability of default of f<strong>in</strong>ancial subsidiaries on thebasis of Merton’s structural model can lead to difficulties. This is because theequity of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial subsidiary may not be traded. For example, FordMotor is traded, whereas its f<strong>in</strong>ancial subsidiary, Ford <strong>Credit</strong>, is not traded.Consider<strong>in</strong>g that the f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g arm of major <strong>in</strong>dustrial corporates is vital tothe survival of both the parent and the subsidiary, one can argue that theequity market takes this relationship <strong>in</strong>to account when valu<strong>in</strong>g the parentcompany. Under this argument, one can assign the same probability ofdefault to both companies when only one of them is traded <strong>in</strong> the market.Recovery RateIn the event of default, bondholders do not receive all of the promised couponand pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments on the bond. Recovery rate for a bond, which isdef<strong>in</strong>ed as the percentage of the face value that can be recovered <strong>in</strong> the eventof default, is of natural <strong>in</strong>terest to <strong>in</strong>vestors. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that credit marketconvention is to ask how much of promised debt is lost rather than howmuch of it is recovered, the term loss given default (LGD), which is def<strong>in</strong>edas one m<strong>in</strong>us recovery rate, is also commonly used <strong>in</strong> the credit risk literature.In general, estimat<strong>in</strong>g the recovery value of a bond <strong>in</strong> the event ofdefault is rather complex. This is because the payments made to bondholderscould take the form of a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of equity and derivative securities,new debt, or modifications to the terms of the surviv<strong>in</strong>g debt. Because theremay be no market for some forms of payments, it may not be feasible tomeasure the recovery value. Moreover, the amount recovered could takeseveral months or even years to materialize and could potentially alsodepend on the relative strength of the negotiat<strong>in</strong>g positions. As a result, estimat<strong>in</strong>ghistorical averages of amounts recovered from defaulted debtrequires mak<strong>in</strong>g some simplify<strong>in</strong>g assumptions.Moody’s, for <strong>in</strong>stance, proxies the recovery rate with the secondary marketprice of the defaulted <strong>in</strong>strument approximately 1 month after the timeof default. 3 The motivation for such a def<strong>in</strong>ition is that many <strong>in</strong>vestors may


76 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSwish to trade out of defaulted bonds and a separate <strong>in</strong>vestor clientele mayacquire these and pursue the legal issues related to recover<strong>in</strong>g money fromdefaulted debt <strong>in</strong>struments. In this context, Moody’s recovery rate proxy canbe <strong>in</strong>terpreted as a transfer price between these two <strong>in</strong>vestor groups.Empirical research on recovery rates suggests that <strong>in</strong>dustrial sector,seniority of the debt, state of the economy, and credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the issuer1 year prior to default are variables that have significant <strong>in</strong>fluence onpotential recovery rates. 4 For example, dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of economic downturns,the recovery rate is usually lower relative to historical averages. Thishas the consequence that there is also a time dimension to the potentialrecovery rates. Differences <strong>in</strong> recovery rates for defaulted debt across<strong>in</strong>dustry sectors arise because the recovery amount depends on the networth of tangible assets the firm has. For <strong>in</strong>stance, firms belong<strong>in</strong>g to<strong>in</strong>dustrial sectors with physical assets, such as public utilities, have higherrecovery rates than the <strong>in</strong>dustrywide average. Empirical results also tend tosuggest that issuers that were rated <strong>in</strong>vestment grade 1 year prior to defaulttend to have higher recovery values than issuers that were rated non<strong>in</strong>vestmentgrade.To <strong>in</strong>corporate the variations <strong>in</strong> the observed recovery rates over timeand between issuers when quantify<strong>in</strong>g credit risk, the standard deviation ofrecovery rates, denoted RR , is taken <strong>in</strong>to account. Includ<strong>in</strong>g the uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty<strong>in</strong> recovery rates has the effect of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g credit risk at the issuer level.Common practice is to use the beta distribution to model the observed variations<strong>in</strong> recovery rates. The advantage of choos<strong>in</strong>g the beta distribution isthat is has a simple functional form, dependent on two parameters, whichallows for high recovery rate outliers observed <strong>in</strong> the empirical data to bemodeled. The beta distribution has support on the <strong>in</strong>terval 0 to 1 and itsdensity function is given by( )()() x 1 (1 x) 1 , 0 x 1f(x, , ) e0, otherwise(5.14)where 0, 0, and () is the gamma function. The mean and varianceof the beta distribution are given, respectively, byand 2 ( ) 2 (1)(5.15)(5.16)


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 77EXHIBIT 5.2 Recovery Rate Statistics on Defaulted Securities (1978 to 2001)Number Median Mean Standard<strong>Bond</strong> Seniority of Issuers (%) (%) Deviation (%)Senior secured 134 57.42 52.97 23.05Senior unsecured 475 42.27 41.71 26.62Senior subord<strong>in</strong>ated 340 31.90 29.68 24.97Subord<strong>in</strong>ated 247 31.96 31.03 22.53Source: E. Altman, A. Resti, and A. Sironi, “Analyz<strong>in</strong>g and Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g DefaultRecovery Rates,” Report submitted to the International Swaps and DerivativesAssociation, December 2001.Exhibit 5.2 shows the empirical estimates of recovery rates on defaultedsecurities cover<strong>in</strong>g the period 1978 to 2001 based on prices at time ofdefault. Note that senior secured debt recovers on average 53 percent of theface value of the debt, whereas senior unsecured debt recovers only around42 percent of face value. The standard deviation of the recovery rates forall seniority classes is roughly around 25 percent.The empirical estimates for average recovery rates tend to vary somewhatdepend<strong>in</strong>g on the data set used and the recovery rate def<strong>in</strong>ition. For<strong>in</strong>stance, the study by Moody’s us<strong>in</strong>g defaulted bond data cover<strong>in</strong>g the period1970 to 2000 suggests that the mean recovery rate for senior securedbonds is 52.6 percent, for senior unsecured bonds is 46.9 percent, and forsubord<strong>in</strong>ated bonds is 31.6 percent.In the numerical examples to be presented <strong>in</strong> this book, I assume thatthe bonds under consideration are senior unsecured debt. Furthermore, Iassume that the standard deviation of the recovery rate is 25 percent andthe average recovery rate is 47 percent, which is closer to Moody’s estimate.Rat<strong>in</strong>g MigrationsThe framework for assess<strong>in</strong>g the issuer’s PD <strong>in</strong>volves estimat<strong>in</strong>g the probabilityassociated with the issuer default<strong>in</strong>g on its promised debt payments.In this framework, the issuer is considered to be <strong>in</strong> one of two states: its currentrat<strong>in</strong>g or the default state. In practice, default is just one of many statesto which the issuer’s rat<strong>in</strong>g can make a transition. The action of rat<strong>in</strong>gagencies can result <strong>in</strong> the issuer’s rat<strong>in</strong>g be<strong>in</strong>g downgraded or upgraded byone or several notches. One can associate the concept of a state with eachrat<strong>in</strong>g grade, so that rat<strong>in</strong>g actions result <strong>in</strong> the transition to one of severalstates. Each rat<strong>in</strong>g action can be viewed as a credit event that changes theperceived probability of default of the issuer. In the credit risk term<strong>in</strong>ology,such a multistate credit event process is described as credit or rat<strong>in</strong>g migration.


78 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSAssociated with rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations are transition probabilities, which modelthe relative frequency with which such credit events occur.Model<strong>in</strong>g the rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations process requires estimat<strong>in</strong>g a matrix oftransition probabilities, which is referred to as the rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix.Each cell <strong>in</strong> the 1-year rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix corresponds to the probabilityof an issuer migrat<strong>in</strong>g from one rat<strong>in</strong>g state to another over the courseof a 12-month horizon. Mathematically speak<strong>in</strong>g, a rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrixis a Markov matrix, which has the property that the sum of all cells <strong>in</strong> anygiven row of the matrix is equal to one. Incorporat<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations<strong>in</strong>to the credit risk-model<strong>in</strong>g framework provides a much richer picture ofchanges <strong>in</strong> the aggregate credit quality of the issuer.The technique used to estimate transition probabilities is similar <strong>in</strong>pr<strong>in</strong>ciple to the estimation of probability of default. For <strong>in</strong>stance, comput<strong>in</strong>gthe 1-year transition probability from the rat<strong>in</strong>g Aa1 to Baa1 requiresfirst determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the number of issuers rated Baa1 that had an Aa1 rat<strong>in</strong>g1 year earlier. Divid<strong>in</strong>g this number by the total number of issuers that wererated Aa1 dur<strong>in</strong>g the previous year gives the 1-year transition probabilitybetween these two rat<strong>in</strong>gs. Aga<strong>in</strong>, if the rat<strong>in</strong>gs of some Aa1 issuers arewithdrawn dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1-year period of <strong>in</strong>terest, then the total number ofAa1 issuers is reduced by this number. Annual transition probabilities calculated<strong>in</strong> this manner are then aggregated over a number of years to estimatethe average historical transition probability. Exhibit 5.3 shows the 1-yearrat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix estimated by Moody’s cover<strong>in</strong>g the period 1983to 2001. In this exhibit, the transition probabilities are expressed <strong>in</strong> percentagesand the column WR refers to the percentage of rat<strong>in</strong>gs that werewithdrawn.The <strong>in</strong>terpretation of the numbers <strong>in</strong> this matrix is the follow<strong>in</strong>g. Thefirst cell <strong>in</strong> the matrix refers to the probability (expressed <strong>in</strong> percentageterms) of rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the rat<strong>in</strong>g grade Aaa 1 year from now. The estimateof this probability is 85 percent on the basis of historical migrationdata. The cell under column A3 <strong>in</strong> the first row of the matrix refers to theprobability of an issuer migrat<strong>in</strong>g from an Aaa rat<strong>in</strong>g to an A3 rat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>1 year. Aga<strong>in</strong>, the estimate of this probability on the basis of historicalmigration data is 0.16 percent. Similarly, the cells <strong>in</strong> the second rowcorrespond to the 1-year migration probabilities of an issuer that is currentlyrated Aa1.Exhibit 5.3 reveals <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation concern<strong>in</strong>g the relative frequencyof rat<strong>in</strong>g downgrades and upgrades. For example, the rat<strong>in</strong>g transitionmatrix suggests that higher rat<strong>in</strong>gs have generally been less likely thanlower rat<strong>in</strong>gs to be revised over 1 year. Another observation is that largeand sudden rat<strong>in</strong>g changes occur <strong>in</strong>frequently. As one moves down the rat<strong>in</strong>gscale, the likelihood of a mult<strong>in</strong>otch rat<strong>in</strong>g change <strong>in</strong>creases. The transitionmatrix also reveals one feature that is somewhat less desirable. This


79Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa–C Default WRAaa 85.00 5.88 2.90 0.47 0.71 0.28 0.16 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 4.56Aa1 2.54 76.02 7.87 6.58 2.31 0.32 0.05 0.18 0.00 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 4.04Aa2 0.70 2.90 77.00 8.39 3.93 1.35 0.58 0.16 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.05 0.08 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 4.85Aa3 0.08 0.61 3.36 77.88 8.89 3.14 0.85 0.24 0.21 0.16 0.00 0.04 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.08 4.38A1 0.03 0.11 0.60 5.53 77.68 7.20 2.88 0.78 0.27 0.13 0.36 0.25 0.05 0.12 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 3.99A2 0.05 0.06 0.29 0.77 5.34 77.47 7.18 2.87 0.80 0.39 0.28 0.10 0.11 0.03 0.07 0.00 0.03 0.02 4.13A3 0.05 0.10 0.05 0.23 1.48 8.26 71.77 6.69 3.65 1.43 0.54 0.19 0.22 0.33 0.05 0.04 0.01 0.00 4.91Baa1 0.08 0.02 0.13 0.18 0.20 2.71 7.67 71.19 7.37 3.14 1.04 0.46 0.35 0.55 0.09 0.00 0.02 0.08 4.73Baa2 0.07 0.10 0.12 0.17 0.17 0.87 3.67 6.90 71.50 7.02 1.68 0.52 0.65 0.48 0.45 0.23 0.03 0.07 5.30Baa3 0.03 0.00 0.03 0.07 0.18 0.57 0.65 3.22 9.33 67.03 6.38 2.59 1.90 0.80 0.31 0.18 0.16 0.43 6.15Ba1 0.08 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.22 0.12 0.67 0.75 2.94 7.68 66.47 4.60 3.88 1.12 1.27 0.81 0.33 0.62 8.39Ba2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.04 0.15 0.13 0.35 0.70 2.30 8.35 63.96 6.20 1.67 3.70 1.35 0.53 0.65 9.88Ba3 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.16 0.17 0.17 0.26 0.69 2.71 5.04 66.66 4.83 5.16 2.22 0.85 2.27 8.74B1 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.06 0.09 0.15 0.07 0.24 0.30 0.42 2.52 5.70 66.89 5.22 4.58 1.78 3.71 8.23B2 0.00 0.00 0.06 0.01 0.11 0.00 0.07 0.17 0.12 0.18 0.29 1.63 2.95 5.75 61.22 7.61 3.69 8.04 8.10B3 0.00 0.00 0.06 0.00 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.11 0.12 0.20 0.18 0.35 1.17 4.02 3.36 62.05 6.84 12.50 8.91Caa–C 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.48 0.48 0.64 0.00 1.36 1.85 1.23 2.87 54.21 26.54 10.36Default 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 100.0 0.00Source: Adapted from Exhibit 13 <strong>in</strong> David T. Hamilton, Richard Cantor, and Sharon Ou, “Default and Recovery Rates of <strong>Corporate</strong>Issuers,” Moody’s Investors Service, February 2002, p. 14. © Moody’s Investors Service, Inc., and/or its affiliates. Repr<strong>in</strong>ted with permission.All rights reserved.EXHIBIT 5.3 Moody’s Average One-Year Rat<strong>in</strong>g Transition Matrix (1983 to 2001)


80 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSconcerns the probability of default for different rat<strong>in</strong>gs, which, contrary toexpectations, does not <strong>in</strong>crease monotonically as one moves down the rat<strong>in</strong>ggrade. For example, the probability of default for an Aa3-rated issuer is0.08 percent, whereas for an A3-rated issuer it is zero and it is only 0.07percent for a Baa2-rated issuer.This raises the follow<strong>in</strong>g important question: Should we be concernedwith the empirical observations that Aa3-rated issuers are more likely todefault than Baa2-rated issuers and that for some rat<strong>in</strong>gs the probability ofdefault is zero? The answer is yes, primarily because this has implicationsfor the calculation of default correlations to be discussed <strong>in</strong> the next chapter.A PD of zero for A3-rated issuers implies that the probability of contemporaneousdefaults of A3-rated issuers and issuers of any other rat<strong>in</strong>g iszero. Clearly, a default probability of zero is undesirable because it leads tonon<strong>in</strong>tuitive results when estimat<strong>in</strong>g credit risk. Therefore it is necessary tomake the follow<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>e tun<strong>in</strong>gs to the rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix shown <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 5.3:Elim<strong>in</strong>ate the column WR <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 5.3 and normalize each row sothat all cells <strong>in</strong> any given row add up to 100 percent.Ref<strong>in</strong>e the result<strong>in</strong>g probabilities under the default column so that theyare monotonically <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g, with the implication that probability ofdefault <strong>in</strong>creases as credit rat<strong>in</strong>g decl<strong>in</strong>es.Readjust the probabilities <strong>in</strong> the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g columns so that each rowrepresents a valid probability vector.The process of delet<strong>in</strong>g the WR column and scal<strong>in</strong>g up the transition probabilitiesso that each row represents a valid probability vector (i.e., all cells<strong>in</strong> the row sum to 1 or equivalently 100 percent) is called normalization. Irefer to the default probabilities for various rat<strong>in</strong>gs derived through the normalizationprocess as the normalized PD. For the purpose of ref<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g thenormalized probabilities so that they <strong>in</strong>crease monotonically as rat<strong>in</strong>gsdecl<strong>in</strong>e, I take <strong>in</strong>to account both Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s normalizeddefault probability estimates. Exhibit 5.4 shows the normalized probabilityof default for various rat<strong>in</strong>g grades based on Moody’s and Standard& Poor’s estimates and the default probabilities to be used when estimat<strong>in</strong>gcredit risk <strong>in</strong> the numerical examples.For issuers <strong>in</strong> the rat<strong>in</strong>g grade Baa1 and lower, the PD values <strong>in</strong> Exhibit5.4 are chosen to reflect the maximum of the estimates of Moody’s andStandard & Poor’s. For issuers with rat<strong>in</strong>gs between Aaa and Aa3, Iassume the default probability <strong>in</strong>creases by 1 basis po<strong>in</strong>t (0.01 percentagepo<strong>in</strong>t) for every one-notch downgrade. From the grade Aa3 to grade A3,PD is assumed to <strong>in</strong>crease by 2 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts for every one-notch downgrade.


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 81EXHIBIT 5.4Normalized One-Year Probability of Default for Various Rat<strong>in</strong>g GradesRat<strong>in</strong>g Standard & Moody’s PD UsedRat<strong>in</strong>g Grade Description Poor’s (%) (%) (%)1 Aaa/AAA 0.00 0.00 0.012 Aa1/AA 0.00 0.00 0.023 Aa2/AA 0.00 0.00 0.034 Aa3/AA 0.03 0.08 0.045 A1/A 0.02 0.00 0.066 A2/A 0.05 0.02 0.087 A3/A 0.05 0.00 0.108 Baa1/BBB 0.13 0.08 0.139 Baa2/BBB 0.23 0.07 0.2310 Baa3/BBB 0.37 0.46 0.4611 Ba1/BB 0.48 0.67 0.6712 Ba2/BB 1.03 0.72 1.0313 Ba3/BB 1.46 2.46 2.4614 B1/B 3.25 3.97 3.9715 B2/B 9.37 8.41 9.3716 B3/B 11.49 13.72 13.7217 Caa–C/CCC 25.25 29.60 29.60With these changes to the default probability estimates, Exhibit 5.5shows the normalized rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix used to quantify credit risk<strong>in</strong> the numerical examples <strong>in</strong> this book.QUANTIFYING CREDIT RISKIn the previous section, I identified the important variables that <strong>in</strong>fluencecredit risk at the security level. In this section, I will focus on quantify<strong>in</strong>gcredit risk at the security level. Most people are familiar with theconcept of risk <strong>in</strong> connection with f<strong>in</strong>ancial securities. In broad terms,risk is associated with potential f<strong>in</strong>ancial loss that can arise from hold<strong>in</strong>gthe security, the exact magnitude of which is difficult to forecast. Asa result, it is common to describe the potential loss <strong>in</strong> value us<strong>in</strong>g anappropriate probability distribution whose mean and standard deviationserve as useful measures for risk quantification.This practice is well known <strong>in</strong> the equities market, where <strong>in</strong>vestorsfocus on market risk measures that model variations <strong>in</strong> stock return. Thisleads to quantify<strong>in</strong>g the market risk measures through expected return andstandard deviation of return. Under the assumption that equity returns arenormally distributed, the realized return lies with<strong>in</strong> one standard deviationof the expected return with two-thirds probability.


82Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa–C DefaultAaa 89.06 6.16 3.04 0.49 0.74 0.29 0.17 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01Aa1 2.65 79.20 8.20 6.86 2.41 0.33 0.05 0.19 0.00 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02Aa2 0.74 3.05 80.90 8.82 4.13 1.42 0.61 0.17 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.05 0.08 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03Aa3 0.08 0.64 3.52 81.48 9.30 3.28 0.89 0.25 0.22 0.17 0.00 0.04 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04A1 0.03 0.11 0.62 5.76 80.88 7.50 3.00 0.81 0.28 0.14 0.37 0.26 0.05 0.12 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.06A2 0.05 0.06 0.30 0.80 5.57 80.75 7.48 2.99 0.83 0.41 0.29 0.11 0.12 0.03 0.07 0.03 0.03 0.08A3 0.05 0.11 0.05 0.24 1.55 8.68 75.40 7.03 3.83 1.50 0.57 0.20 0.23 0.35 0.05 0.05 0.01 0.10Baa1 0.08 0.02 0.14 0.19 0.21 2.84 8.04 74.68 7.73 3.29 1.09 0.48 0.37 0.58 0.09 0.02 0.02 0.13Baa2 0.07 0.11 0.13 0.18 0.18 0.92 3.87 7.27 75.35 7.40 1.77 0.55 0.69 0.51 0.47 0.27 0.03 0.23Baa3 0.03 0.00 0.03 0.08 0.19 0.61 0.69 3.42 9.92 71.29 6.79 2.76 2.02 0.85 0.33 0.36 0.17 0.46Ba1 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.24 0.13 0.73 0.82 3.20 8.36 72.31 5.00 4.22 1.22 1.38 1.24 0.36 0.67Ba2 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.04 0.16 0.14 0.39 0.77 2.53 9.18 70.35 6.82 1.84 4.07 2.07 0.58 1.03Ba3 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.17 0.19 0.19 0.28 0.75 2.94 5.47 72.38 5.25 5.60 3.34 0.92 2.46B1 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.06 0.10 0.16 0.08 0.26 0.32 0.45 2.69 6.09 71.52 5.58 6.80 1.90 3.97B2 0.00 0.00 0.06 0.01 0.11 0.00 0.07 0.18 0.12 0.19 0.30 1.69 3.05 5.95 63.38 11.70 3.82 9.37B3 0.00 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.02 0.04 0.07 0.12 0.13 0.22 0.20 0.38 1.28 4.41 3.69 68.14 7.51 13.72Caa–C 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.54 0.54 0.71 0.00 1.52 2.06 1.37 3.20 60.46 29.60Default 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 100.0EXHIBIT 5.5 Normalized One-Year Rat<strong>in</strong>g Transition Matrix


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 83EXHIBIT 5.6Typical Shape of the <strong>Credit</strong> Loss DistributionFrequency of loss0<strong>Credit</strong> lossQuantify<strong>in</strong>g credit risk at the security level is similar <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple.Unlike the case for equities, corporate bond <strong>in</strong>vestors focus on the distributionof potential losses that can result from the issuer-specific creditevents. Borrow<strong>in</strong>g the pr<strong>in</strong>ciple from the equities market, it has becomecommon practice to quantify credit risk at the security level through themean and the standard deviation of the loss distribution. However, there isan important difference between the two risk measures. This perta<strong>in</strong>s to thedistribution of credit loss, which, unlike for market risk, is far from be<strong>in</strong>ga normal distribution. Hence, deviations from the expected loss by onestandard deviation can occur more frequently than on one <strong>in</strong> three occasions.<strong>Credit</strong> market convention is to refer to the standard deviation of lossresult<strong>in</strong>g from credit events as unexpected loss (UL) and the average loss asexpected loss (EL). Exhibit 5.6 shows the typical shape of the distributionof credit losses.In this section, I discuss how expected and unexpected loss as used toquantify credit risk at the security level can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed. Depend<strong>in</strong>g onwhether the loss distribution takes <strong>in</strong>to account the changes <strong>in</strong> securityprices result<strong>in</strong>g from rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations or not, we can compute two sets ofloss variables, one <strong>in</strong> the default mode and another <strong>in</strong> the migration mode.I now discuss quantification of credit risk <strong>in</strong> both these modes.Expected Loss Under Default ModeExpected loss under the default mode of a bond is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the averageloss the bondholder can expect to <strong>in</strong>cur if the issuer goes bankrupt. Becausedefault probability estimates are based on a 1-year hold<strong>in</strong>g period, expectedloss is also expressed over a 1-year period. In practice, the issuer couldactually default at any time dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1-year horizon. Because a bond portfoliomanager is usually <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the worst-case loss scenario, which


84 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 5.7 <strong>Bond</strong> Price DistributionUnder the Default ModeP dirtyδ = 1δ = 0ψP dirtycorresponds to the issuer default<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the immediate future, I use the 1-yearPD to quantify the worst-case loss. This has the implication that one canquantify credit risk us<strong>in</strong>g the current trad<strong>in</strong>g price for the bond rather thanits 1-year forward price. Because the portfolio manager’s goal is to managerelative risk versus a benchmark, the use of 1-year PD <strong>in</strong> conjunction withcurrent trad<strong>in</strong>g prices does not bias the relative risk estimates. However,this assumption leads to considerable simplification <strong>in</strong> quantify<strong>in</strong>g creditrisk because deriv<strong>in</strong>g forward yield curves for various credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs is quitetedious.The estimate of expected loss for a security depends on three variables:probability of default of the issuer, the average recovery rate, and the nom<strong>in</strong>alexposure (NE) to the security. One can th<strong>in</strong>k of the default process asbe<strong>in</strong>g a Bernoulli random variable that takes the value 0 or 1. The value1 signals a default and the value 0 signals no default. Conditionalupon default, the recovery rate is a random variable whose mean recoveryrate is RR. Exhibit 5.7 pictorially depicts the default process and the recoveryvalues. In this exhibit, P dirty denotes the dirty price (clean price plus accrued<strong>in</strong>terest) for a $1 face value of the bond.Exhibit 5.7 <strong>in</strong>dicates that if the issuer defaults, the price of the bondwill be equal to its recovery rate , which is a random variable. If the issuerdoes not default, the bond can be sold for a value equal to its current dirtyprice P dirty . In this default mode framework, the price of the risky debt canbe written asP Pdirty I [0] I [1](5.17)In equation (5.17), I is the <strong>in</strong>dicator function of the default process. For thepurpose of quantify<strong>in</strong>g credit risk, the variable of <strong>in</strong>terest is the credit lossresult<strong>in</strong>g from hold<strong>in</strong>g the corporate bond. This is a random variable /,which is given by/ Pdirty P P dirty P dirty I [0] I [1] (5.18)


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 85Tak<strong>in</strong>g expectations on both sides of equation (5.18) makes it possible tocompute the expected loss aris<strong>in</strong>g from credit risk. This is given byEL E(/ ) P dirty P dirty (1 PD) E( I [1] )(5.19)Note that comput<strong>in</strong>g the expected loss requires tak<strong>in</strong>g the expectation of theproduct of two random variables, the recovery rate process and the defaultprocess. Knowledge of the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of these two random variables isrequired to compute this expectation. Most credit risk models make the simplify<strong>in</strong>gassumption that these two random variables are <strong>in</strong>dependent. If onemakes this assumption, one gets the follow<strong>in</strong>g equation for expected loss:EL P dirty PD RR PD PD (P dirty RR)(5.20)Recall that P dirty is the dirty price of the bond for $1 nom<strong>in</strong>al and RR <strong>in</strong>equation (5.20) is the mean recovery rate, which is expressed as a fractionof the face value of the debt. It is important to note that the quantity(P dirty RR) is different from LGD, which is def<strong>in</strong>ed as one m<strong>in</strong>us therecovery rate. The loss on default (LD) captures this new quantity:LD P dirty RR (5.21)Note that loss on default is identical to loss given default if the dirty priceof the bond is equal to one. In all other circumstances, these two quantitiesare not the same.Equation (5.20) was derived under the assumption that the nom<strong>in</strong>alexposure is $1. The expected loss from credit risk for a nom<strong>in</strong>al exposureequal to NE is given byEL NE PD LD (5.22)The use of the quantity LD rather than LGD <strong>in</strong> def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g expected loss mightraise some doubts <strong>in</strong> the m<strong>in</strong>d of the reader. To clear these doubts, considerthe follow<strong>in</strong>g example, which illustrates why LD is more appropriate thanLGD <strong>in</strong> the context of bond portfolio management.Consider the case of a bond portfolio manager who has the option to<strong>in</strong>vest $1 million either <strong>in</strong> a bond with dirty price $100 (issuer A) or <strong>in</strong> abond with dirty price $80 (issuer B). In the latter case, the portfolio managerbuys $1.25 million nom<strong>in</strong>al value of issuer B’s bond to fully <strong>in</strong>vest the$1 million. Assume that both issuers default with<strong>in</strong> the next 1 year and therecovery value is $50 for $100 face value of exposure. If the portfolio


86 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSmanager had <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> issuer A’s bond, he or she would recover $500,000because the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure is $1 million. On the other hand, if the portfoliomanager <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> issuer B’s bond, then the amount recovered wouldbe $625,000. This is because the portfolio manager has a nom<strong>in</strong>al exposureof $1.25 million of issuer B’s bond. Clearly, from the portfolio manager’sperspective, the credit loss result<strong>in</strong>g from an <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> issuer A’s bondis $500,000, whereas the credit loss from an <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> issuer B’s bondis only $375,000, although both <strong>in</strong>vestments recovered 50 percent of theface value of debt. Use of the quantity LD correctly identifies the losses <strong>in</strong>both circumstances, whereas the LGD def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>in</strong>dicates that the losses are$500,000 for issuer A’s bond and $625,000 for issuer B’s bond. In practice,LGD is used <strong>in</strong> conjunction with the exposure amount of the transaction toidentify the expected loss. However, this def<strong>in</strong>ition also <strong>in</strong>correctly identifiesthe losses as be<strong>in</strong>g identical for both bonds <strong>in</strong> this example.Unexpected Loss Under Default ModeThe expected loss on the bond is the average loss that the <strong>in</strong>vestor canexpect to <strong>in</strong>cur over the course of a 1-year period. However, the actual lossmay well exceed this average loss over certa<strong>in</strong> time periods. The potentialdeviation from the expected loss that the <strong>in</strong>vestor can expect to <strong>in</strong>cur isquantified <strong>in</strong> terms of the standard deviation of the loss variable def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>equation (5.18). <strong>Credit</strong> market convention is to refer to the standard deviationof loss as unexpected loss. Hence, to derive the unexpected loss formula,one needs to compute the standard deviation of the random variable/. To facilitate this computation, one rewrites equation (5.18) as follows:/ Pdirty P dirty (1 I [1] ) I [1] I [1] (P dirty )(5.23)Recall<strong>in</strong>g a standard result from probability theory, one can write the varianceof any random variable z as the difference between the expected valueof the random variable squared m<strong>in</strong>us the square of its expected value. Inequation form, this is given by 2 z E(z 2 ) [E(z)] 2(5.24)Aga<strong>in</strong> make the simplify<strong>in</strong>g assumption that the default and recovery rateprocesses are <strong>in</strong>dependent <strong>in</strong> deriv<strong>in</strong>g the unexpected loss formula. Underthis assumption, one can write the variance of the random variable / asVar(/ ) E(I 2 [1]) E[(P dirty ) 2 ] [E(I [1] )] 2 [E(P dirty )] 2(5.25)


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 87Tak<strong>in</strong>g expected values and us<strong>in</strong>g the relation (5.24) results <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>gsimplification of equation (5.25).Var(/ ) [ 2 PD PD 2 ] [ 2 RR LD 2 ] PD 2 LD 2(5.26)In this equation, 2 PD is the variance of the Bernoulli random variable ,which is given by 2 PD PD (1 PD)(5.27)Simplify<strong>in</strong>g the terms <strong>in</strong> equation (5.26), it can be shown that unexpectedloss, which is the standard deviation of the loss variable, is given byUL 2PD 2 RR LD 2 2 PD(5.28)This formula for unexpected loss assumes that the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure isequal to $1. For a nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure equal to NE, the unexpected loss atthe security level is given byUL NE 2PD 2 RR LD 2 2 PD(5.29)On the Independence Assumption In deriv<strong>in</strong>g the expressions for expected andunexpected losses on a bond result<strong>in</strong>g from credit risk, I made the simplify<strong>in</strong>gassumption that the default process and the recovery rate process are<strong>in</strong>dependent. One needs to ask whether this assumption is reasonable.Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g theoretical models on credit risk does not give a def<strong>in</strong>itiveanswer to this question. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> Merton’s framework, the defaultprocess of a firm is driven by the value of the firm’s assets. The risk of afirm’s default is therefore explicitly l<strong>in</strong>ked to the variability <strong>in</strong> the firm’sasset value. In this setup, both the default process and the recovery rate area function of the structural characteristics of the firm, and one can showthat PD and RR are <strong>in</strong>versely related.The reduced-form models, unlike the structural models, do not conditiondefault on the value of the firm. The default and recovery processes aremodeled <strong>in</strong>dependently of the structural features of the firm and are furtherassumed to be <strong>in</strong>dependent of each other. This <strong>in</strong>dependence assumptionbetween default and recovery processes, which is fundamental to reducedformmodels, is pervasive <strong>in</strong> credit value at risk models.Empirical results on the relationship between default and recovery valuestend to suggest that these two variables are negatively correlated. The<strong>in</strong>tuition beh<strong>in</strong>d this result is that both default rate and recovery rate may


88 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSdepend on certa<strong>in</strong> structural factors. For <strong>in</strong>stance, if a borrower defaults onthe debt payments, the recovery rate depends on the net worth of the firm’sassets. This net worth, which is usually a function of prevail<strong>in</strong>g economicconditions, is lower dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of recession. In contrast, dur<strong>in</strong>g recession,the probability of default of issuers tends to <strong>in</strong>crease. The comb<strong>in</strong>ationof these two effects results <strong>in</strong> a negative correlation between defaultand recovery rates.More recent empirical research on the relationship between default andrecovery rate processes suggests that a simple microeconomic <strong>in</strong>terpretationbased on supply and demand tends to drive aggregate recovery rate values. 5In particular, dur<strong>in</strong>g high-default years, the supply of defaulted securitiestends to exceed demand, which <strong>in</strong> turn drives secondary market pricesdown. Because RR values are based on bond prices shortly after default, theobserved recovery rates are lower when there is an excess supply of defaultedsecurities.To <strong>in</strong>corporate the empirical evidence that recovery values decreasewhen default rates are high, one has to identify periods when PD is high relativeto normal levels. If PD values are determ<strong>in</strong>ed on the basis of historicalaverage default rates as is done by rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies, it is difficult to dist<strong>in</strong>guishbetween low- and high-default periods. On the other hand, if astructural approach is used to estimate PD values as is done by KMV Corporation,it is possible to signal periods when PD values are higher than historicalaverage levels. This <strong>in</strong>formation can then be <strong>in</strong>corporated to determ<strong>in</strong>ethe appropriate recovery rates to be used. Such an approach amountsto the use of a regime-switch<strong>in</strong>g model to determ<strong>in</strong>e the average recoveryrates. Aga<strong>in</strong>, empirical estimates tend to suggest that bond recovery ratescould decl<strong>in</strong>e roughly by 20 percent from historical averages dur<strong>in</strong>g periodsof economic downturn.In the numerical examples <strong>in</strong> this book, I estimate the relevant creditrisk measures for two different economic regimes: the normal economy andrecession. Under recession, I assume that the recovery rates are 20 percentlower than the average recovery rates.Expected Loss Under Migration ModeTo derive the formula for expected loss under the default mode, I took <strong>in</strong>toconsideration the credit event that results <strong>in</strong> the issuer default<strong>in</strong>g on debtpayments. In general, this is not the only credit event the bondholder experiencesthat <strong>in</strong>fluences the market price of the bond. More frequent arecredit events that result <strong>in</strong> rat<strong>in</strong>g upgrades or downgrades of the bondissuer. These credit events correspond to a change <strong>in</strong> the op<strong>in</strong>ion of the rat<strong>in</strong>gagencies concern<strong>in</strong>g the creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess of the issuer. Because rat<strong>in</strong>gchanges are issuer-specific credit events, the associated bond price changes


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 89fall under credit risk. Includ<strong>in</strong>g the price risk result<strong>in</strong>g from rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations<strong>in</strong> the calculation of potential credit losses is referred to as the creditrisk under the migration mode.In practice, a change <strong>in</strong> bond price can be either positive or negativedepend<strong>in</strong>g on whether the rat<strong>in</strong>g change results <strong>in</strong> an upgrade or a downgrade,respectively. However, I use the term credit loss generically to referto a change <strong>in</strong> bond price as a result of a credit event. Before proceed<strong>in</strong>g toderive the formula that quantifies expected loss under the migration mode,I <strong>in</strong>dicate how the price change result<strong>in</strong>g from a credit event can be estimated.Estimat<strong>in</strong>g Price Changes Practitioners familiar with the pric<strong>in</strong>g of corporatebonds know that the issuer’s rat<strong>in</strong>g does not fully expla<strong>in</strong> yield differentialsbetween bonds of similar maturities. Us<strong>in</strong>g the Lehman Brothers corporatebond database, Elton, Gruber, Agrawal, and Mann found that pric<strong>in</strong>gerrors can vary from 34 cents per $100 for Aa f<strong>in</strong>ancials to greater than$1.17 per $100 for Baa <strong>in</strong>dustrials. 6 Their study suggests that the follow<strong>in</strong>gfactors have an important <strong>in</strong>fluence on observed price differentials betweencorporate bonds:The f<strong>in</strong>er rat<strong>in</strong>g categories <strong>in</strong>troduced by the major rat<strong>in</strong>g agencieswhen comb<strong>in</strong>ed with the bonds’ maturity.Differences between Standard and Poor’s and Moody’s rat<strong>in</strong>gs for theissuers.Differences <strong>in</strong> expected recovery rate for the bonds.The coupon on the bonds due to different tax treatment.Whether the bonds are new or have traded for more than 1 year.These observations <strong>in</strong>dicate that one cannot use generic yield curves forvarious rat<strong>in</strong>g grades to reprice bonds when the issuer’s rat<strong>in</strong>g changes.One has to adopt a different technique to estimate the price risk result<strong>in</strong>gfrom rat<strong>in</strong>g changes. It is important to bear <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong> the context ofcredit risk quantification, the objective is to estimate approximate pricechanges from rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations rather than capture the correct trad<strong>in</strong>gprice for the bond. To this end, rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations should result <strong>in</strong> a pricechange that is consistent with perceived change <strong>in</strong> the creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess ofthe issuer.The technique adopted here to estimate the change <strong>in</strong> bond price due toa rat<strong>in</strong>g change uses the current modified duration and convexity of thebond. To determ<strong>in</strong>e the change <strong>in</strong> yield associated with a rat<strong>in</strong>g change, Iassume that there exists a fixed yield spread between each rat<strong>in</strong>g grade thatis a function of the debt issue’s seniority. These yield spreads are taken relativeto the government yield curve. If the modified duration of the bond is


90 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSdenoted by D and the convexity by C, then the change <strong>in</strong> price of the bonddue to a change y <strong>in</strong> the bond yield as a result of the rat<strong>in</strong>g change is givenbyPrice change P dirty D y 0.5 P dirty C y 2(5.30)Because our <strong>in</strong>terest is <strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g the loss result<strong>in</strong>g from the rat<strong>in</strong>gchange to quantify credit risk, the follow<strong>in</strong>g equation is the one that isrelevant:P P dirty D y 0.5 P dirty C y 2(5.31)The advantage of such a technique is that it reta<strong>in</strong>s price differentialsobserved <strong>in</strong> the market between bonds with similar maturity and creditrat<strong>in</strong>g when the issuer migrates to a different rat<strong>in</strong>g grade. Exhibit 5.8shows the <strong>in</strong>dicative yield spreads relative to government bonds for differentrat<strong>in</strong>g grades as a function of the seniority of the debt issue. Theseyield spreads are used <strong>in</strong> conjunction with the current duration and convexityof the bond to estimate the price change result<strong>in</strong>g from a rat<strong>in</strong>gmigration.EXHIBIT 5.8Yield Spreads for Different Rat<strong>in</strong>g Grades and Debt Seniority aRat<strong>in</strong>g Grade Rat<strong>in</strong>g Description Senior Unsecured (bp) Subord<strong>in</strong>ated (bp)1 Aaa/AAA 15 202 Aa1/AA 30 403 Aa2/AA 45 604 Aa3/AA 60 805 A1/A 75 1006 A2/A 90 1207 A3/A 105 1408 Baa1/BBB 130 1809 Baa2/BBB 155 22010 Baa3/BBB 180 26011 Ba1/BB 230 33012 Ba2/BB 280 41013 Ba3/BB 330 48014 B1/B 430 61015 B2/B 530 74016 B3/B 630 87017 Caa–C/CCC 780 1040a bp, basis po<strong>in</strong>ts.


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 91Deriv<strong>in</strong>g Expected Loss Unlike <strong>in</strong> the case of the default mode, the issuer canmigrate to one of several rat<strong>in</strong>g grades under the migration mode dur<strong>in</strong>g thecourse of the year. Associated with these rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations are discrete transitionprobabilities that constitute the rows of the rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrixgiven <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 5.5. In the rat<strong>in</strong>g migration framework, the transition probabilitiesrepresent historical averages and can be treated as determ<strong>in</strong>isticvariables. The random variables here are the credit losses that the bondholder<strong>in</strong>curs when the issuer rat<strong>in</strong>g changes. The expected value of the creditloss for a rat<strong>in</strong>g change from the ith grade to the kth grade is given byP ik P dirty D y ik 0.5 P dirty C y 2 ik(5.32)y ikIn equation (5.32), denotes the yield change when the issuer rat<strong>in</strong>gchanges from grade i to grade k. When the issuer migrates to the default state,the credit loss P ik is equal to the loss on default LD. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that thereare 18 rat<strong>in</strong>g grades <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the default state, the expected loss under the rat<strong>in</strong>gmigration mode for an issuer whose current credit rat<strong>in</strong>g is i is given by18EL a p ik P ikk1(5.33)In equation (5.33), p ik denotes the 1-year transition probability of migrat<strong>in</strong>gfrom rat<strong>in</strong>g grade i to rat<strong>in</strong>g grade k. This equation quantifies theexpected loss over a 1-year horizon for a nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure of $1. For anom<strong>in</strong>al exposure NE, the expected loss under migration mode is given by18EL NE a p ik P ikk1(5.34)Unexpected Loss Under Migration ModeBy def<strong>in</strong>ition, the unexpected loss under the migration mode is the standarddeviation of the credit loss variable. The loss variable under the migrationmode is given by18/ a p ik P ikk1(5.35)In equation (5.35), P ik denotes the credit loss when the credit rat<strong>in</strong>gchanges from grade i to grade k, which is regarded as a random variable.The expected value of this random variable is P ik and its variance isdenoted by 2 ik . When k is equal to the default state, ik is equal to RR,which is the standard deviation of the recovery rate. Recall<strong>in</strong>g equation


92 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS(5.24), one can write the variance of the loss variable asVar(/ 18) E a a p ik P 2 18ik b c E a ak1k1p ik P 2ik bd(5.36)Tak<strong>in</strong>g expectations and mak<strong>in</strong>g use of the relation (5.24) once more givesthe follow<strong>in</strong>g expression for the variance of the loss variable:Var(/ 1818) a p ik AP 2 ik 2 ikB a ak1k12p ik P ik b(5.37)If one assumes that there is no uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty associated with the credit lossesexcept <strong>in</strong> the default state, all 2 terms <strong>in</strong> equation (5.37) drop out otherthan 2 ikRR . Mak<strong>in</strong>g this assumption and not<strong>in</strong>g that p ik is equal to PD whenk is the default state gives the unexpected loss under the migration mode fora nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure NE:1818UL NE PD 2BRR a p ik P 2 ik a ak1k12p ik P ik b(5.38)NUMERICAL EXAMPLEIn this section, I give a numerical example to illustrate the computations ofexpected and unexpected losses under the default mode and the migrationmode. The security level details of the example are given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 5.9.Because the mean recovery rate is assumed to be 47 percent, the loss ondefault for this security is equal to 0.5833 for $1 nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure. Theprobability of default for this security is equal to 0.10 percent, whichEXHIBIT 5.9DescriptionSecurity-Level Details of Example ConsideredValueIssuer rat<strong>in</strong>g gradeA3Settlement date 24 April 2002<strong>Bond</strong> maturity date 15 February 2007Coupon rate 6.91%Dirty price for $1 nom<strong>in</strong>al 1.0533Nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure $1,000,000Modified duration 4.021Convexity 19.75Mean recovery rate 47%Volatility of RR 25%


Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 93corresponds to the last column <strong>in</strong> row A3 of the transition matrix given <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 5.5. The expected and unexpected losses <strong>in</strong> the default mode whenPD 0.001 are given as follows:EL NE PD LD 1,000,000 0.001 0.5833 $583.3UL NE 2PD 2 RR LD 2 2 PD 1,000,000 20.001 0.25 2 0.5833 2 0.001 (1 0.001) $20,059.88Under the migration mode, the breakdown of the calculations <strong>in</strong>volved<strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g expected and unexpected losses is given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 5.10. Theexpected loss under the migration mode is given by18EL NE a p ik P ikk1 1,000,000 0.003012 $3012EXHIBIT 5.10 Calculation of Expected Loss and Unexpected Loss Under theMigration ModeGradeP ik (%)y ik (%)P ikp ik P ikp ik P 2 ik1 0.05 0.90 0.0390 0.000019 7.590E 072 0.11 0.75 0.0323 0.000036 1.151E 063 0.05 0.60 0.0258 0.000013 3.325E 074 0.24 0.45 0.0193 0.000046 8.912E 075 1.55 0.30 0.0128 0.000198 2.539E 066 8.68 0.15 0.0064 0.000553 3.529E 067 75.40 0.00 0.0000 0.000000 0.000E 008 7.03 0.25 0.0105 0.000740 7.785E 069 3.83 0.50 0.0209 0.000801 1.676E 0510 1.50 0.75 0.0312 0.000468 1.458E 0511 0.57 1.25 0.0513 0.000293 1.501E 0512 0.20 1.75 0.0709 0.000142 1.006E 0513 0.23 2.25 0.0900 0.000207 1.864E 0514 0.35 3.25 0.1267 0.000443 5.615E 0515 0.05 4.25 0.1612 0.000081 1.299E 0516 0.05 5.25 0.1937 0.000097 1.876E 0517 0.01 6.75 0.2385 0.000024 5.688E 0618 0.10 0.5833 0.000583 3.402E 04Sum 0.003012 5.259E 04


94 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSThe unexpected loss under the migration mode is given by1818UL NE PD 2BRR a p ik P 2 ik a ak1 1,000,000 20.001 0.25 2 5.259 10 4 0.003012 2 $24,069.2It is useful to note here that under the migration mode the expected loss is significantlyhigher. The <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the unexpected loss <strong>in</strong> the migration mode isonly around 20 percent relative to the unexpected loss under the default mode.k12p ik P ik bQUESTIONS1. The asset value of a firm is $12 million and the face value of its debt is$10 million. Assum<strong>in</strong>g the annualized growth rate and the volatility ofasset returns are 5 and 10 percent, respectively, compute the 1-yearprobability of default of the firm us<strong>in</strong>g Merton’s approach.2. Expla<strong>in</strong> the practical problems associated with the use of Merton’sapproach to determ<strong>in</strong>e a firm’s probability of default. How does theKMV approach resolve these problems?3. What are the relative merits of the structural and empirical approachesto determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g probability of default?4. How are recovery rates on defaulted bonds estimated? What factors<strong>in</strong>fluence the recovery rate on a bond?5. What are rat<strong>in</strong>g outlooks? Do changes <strong>in</strong> rat<strong>in</strong>g outlooks <strong>in</strong>fluencebond prices? Expla<strong>in</strong> why or why not.6. A senior unsecured bond is trad<strong>in</strong>g at a dirty price of $103.50 and theprobability of default of the issuer is 20 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. Assum<strong>in</strong>g a meanrecovery rate of 47 percent and a volatility of recovery rate of 25 percent,compute the expected and unexpected losses under the defaultmode for a $10 million nom<strong>in</strong>al amount of the bond held.7. What is the empirical evidence on the relationship between recoveryrates and default rates? Do reduced-form models take this empiricalrelationship <strong>in</strong>to account <strong>in</strong> model<strong>in</strong>g credit risk?8. Expla<strong>in</strong> the practical difficulties <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g price changesus<strong>in</strong>g generic yield curves for different rat<strong>in</strong>g categories.9. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that the rat<strong>in</strong>g of the bond <strong>in</strong> Question 6 is A2, compute theexpected and unexpected losses under the migration mode. For the calculations,use the rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 5.5 and the yieldspreads for different rat<strong>in</strong>g categories given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 5.8. The modifiedduration and convexity of the bond are 4 years and 20, respectively.


CHAPTER 6Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong>The focus <strong>in</strong> the previous chapter was primarily on identify<strong>in</strong>g the elementsof credit risk and quantify<strong>in</strong>g credit risk <strong>in</strong> terms of expected andunexpected losses at the security level. A natural extension of the analysispresented <strong>in</strong> the previous chapter is to quantify credit risk when an <strong>in</strong>vestorholds more than one corporate bond. In this case, one has to model the comovementof credit migration and defaults between two or more bonds.This leads to the topic of correlated credit events, which are fundamental tothe model<strong>in</strong>g of portfolio credit risk. In practice, measur<strong>in</strong>g these correlationsdirectly is difficult, if not impossible. Standard techniques used to estimatethem follow an <strong>in</strong>direct approach that makes use of the correlationbetween variables that drive credit events. The variable that is usually consideredto drive credit events is the asset returns of the firm. Because assetreturns are not directly observable, the method used to estimate asset returncorrelation between different obligors is a much-debated topic. Furthermore,the choice of the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution function for asset returns of differentissuers has a strong <strong>in</strong>fluence on the estimate of portfolio credit risk.The appropriate jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution function to be used is still a hotly debatedtopic.In this chapter I develop the relevant equations for comput<strong>in</strong>g portfoliocredit risk under both the default mode and the credit migration mode.I <strong>in</strong>dicate how the loss correlation between obligor pairs, which is requiredto compute portfolio credit risk, can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed. I also give a simpletechnique for deriv<strong>in</strong>g approximate asset return correlations between obligorpairs. F<strong>in</strong>ally, I provide numerical examples to illustrate the various conceptspresented <strong>in</strong> this chapter.QUANTIFYING PORTFOLIO CREDIT RISKIn Chapter 5, credit risk at the security level was quantified <strong>in</strong> terms ofthe mean and the standard deviation of the loss distribution result<strong>in</strong>gfrom price changes due to credit events. Quantification of credit risk at95


96 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSthe portfolio level follows a similar approach. Once aga<strong>in</strong> one is <strong>in</strong>terested<strong>in</strong> the loss distribution of the portfolio due to price changes of <strong>in</strong>dividualbonds aris<strong>in</strong>g from credit events. The mean and the standard deviation ofthe portfolio loss distribution, denoted expected portfolio loss (EL P ) andunexpected portfolio loss (UL P ), are used to quantify portfolio credit risk.To derive the expressions for expected and unexpected losses for theportfolio, consider a two-obligor portfolio for purposes of illustration. Let/ i denote the loss variable for a nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure NE i to a bond issued bythe ith obligor <strong>in</strong> the portfolio that has an expected loss EL i and unexpectedloss UL i . An <strong>in</strong>vestor hold<strong>in</strong>g the two-obligor portfolio is faced with a lossdistribution given by/ P / 1 / 2(6.1)The expected portfolio loss is given byEL P E(/ 1 / 2) EL 1 EL 2(6.2)The variance of the portfolio loss distribution is given byVar(/ P) E[(/ 1 / 2) 2 ] [E(/ 1 / 2)] 2 EA/ 21 B EA/ 2 2 B 2E(/ 1/ 2) EL 1 2 EL 2 2 2EL 1 EL 2(6.3)It is easy to verify that this equation simplifies to the follow<strong>in</strong>g relation:Var(/ P) UL 2 1 UL 2 2 2E(/ 1/ 2) 2EL 1 EL 2(6.4)Based on a standard result <strong>in</strong> probability theory, the correlation between thetwo random variables/ and1 / 2 , which is referred to as the loss correlation,is given by / 12 E(/ 1/ 2) EL 1 EL 2UL 1 UL 2(6.5)With the use of equation (6.5), the variance of the portfolio loss distributionsimplifies toVar(/ P) UL 1 2 UL 2 2 2 / 12 UL 1 UL 2(6.6)Because by def<strong>in</strong>ition the unexpected portfolio loss is the standard deviationof the portfolio loss distribution, for the two-obligor portfolio this is


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 97given byUL P 2UL 1 2 UL 2 2 2 / 12 UL 1 UL 2(6.7)When an <strong>in</strong>vestor is hold<strong>in</strong>g bonds issued by n obligors <strong>in</strong> the portfolio, theexpected and the unexpected portfolio loss are given, respectively, byEL P ani1EL <strong>in</strong> nUL P B a a / ik UL i UL ki1 k1(6.8)(6.9)In equation (6.9), when i k, one sets / ik 1. Because <strong>in</strong> practice bondportfolio managers tend to hold more than one bond issued by the sameobligor <strong>in</strong> the portfolio, equation (6.9) must be generalized to <strong>in</strong>cludesuch cases. To do this, it is tempt<strong>in</strong>g to apply the constra<strong>in</strong>t / ik 1 whenthe ith bond’s issuer is the same as the kth bond’s issuer <strong>in</strong> equation (6.9).However, the loss correlation between two bonds of the same issuer isusually not equal to one. In fact, the forego<strong>in</strong>g equations are equallyapplicable to any n-bond portfolio where the number of obligors is usuallyless than n.Remarks In deriv<strong>in</strong>g the expressions for expected loss and the unexpectedloss for the portfolio, I have made no assumption regard<strong>in</strong>g the loss modeunder which the portfolio loss distribution is computed. In fact, the equationsfor expected and unexpected portfolio loss given by (6.8) and (6.9),respectively, are applicable to both the default mode and the credit migrationmode. If, for <strong>in</strong>stance, the expected loss and unexpected loss at thesecurity level are computed <strong>in</strong> the credit migration mode, then equations(6.8) and (6.9) capture the expected loss and the unexpected loss of theportfolio <strong>in</strong> the credit migration mode.Readers familiar with Markowitz portfolio theory will immediatelyrecognize some similarities between market risk and credit risk. Whereas <strong>in</strong>market risk the measures of <strong>in</strong>terest are the expected return and the standarddeviation of return of the portfolio, <strong>in</strong> credit risk the measures of <strong>in</strong>terestare the expected loss and the standard deviation loss of the portfolio.Apart from this conceptual similarity <strong>in</strong> terms of risk quantification, thereare some major differences between market and credit risk. For <strong>in</strong>stance,the distribution of security returns can be closely approximated us<strong>in</strong>g a normaldistribution function. The distribution of credit loss, however, is farfrom be<strong>in</strong>g a normal distribution function.


98 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSThe other major difference concerns the complexity <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> comput<strong>in</strong>gmarket and credit risk at the portfolio level. For <strong>in</strong>stance, comput<strong>in</strong>gthe standard deviation of portfolio returns under market risk requires knowledgeof the correlation between security returns. Given historical time seriesof security returns, it is fairly straightforward to compute the correlationbetween security returns. Such a simple calculation is not possible for creditrisk, where the time series of <strong>in</strong>terest is the credit loss on bonds for variousissuers. This is because the occurrence of credit losses is quite <strong>in</strong>frequent,and, furthermore, certa<strong>in</strong> issuer’s bonds may not have suffered acredit loss <strong>in</strong> recent history. As a consequence, direct estimation of the losscorrelation between issuer pairs is seldom possible, and therefore <strong>in</strong>directmethods are mostly used to <strong>in</strong>fer loss correlation. It is useful to note herethat the value of loss correlation computed under the default mode is differentfrom the loss correlation computed under the migration mode forany given obligor pair.In connection with portfolio credit risk, most readers are familiar withthe term default correlation, which is commonly used <strong>in</strong>stead of loss correlationto compute the portfolio’s unexpected loss. Although loss correlationand default correlation are closely related, they are not the same. In the nextsection, I discuss <strong>in</strong> detail default correlation and derive its relationship toloss correlation under the default mode. Methods for estimat<strong>in</strong>g defaultcorrelation are also discussed.DEFAULT CORRELATIONIn broad terms, default correlation measures the strength of the default relationshipbetween two obligors. It answers the important question of howthe default by one obligor can <strong>in</strong>fluence the contemporaneous default ofother obligors. An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> default correlation between two obligors<strong>in</strong>creases the unexpected loss of a two-bond portfolio assum<strong>in</strong>g all otherparameters rema<strong>in</strong> the same.Formally, default correlation between two obligors is def<strong>in</strong>ed as thecorrelation between the default <strong>in</strong>dicators for these two obligors over somespecified <strong>in</strong>terval of time, this be<strong>in</strong>g typically 1 year. Denote the default <strong>in</strong>dicatorfor the ith obligor by the Bernoulli random variable i , which takesthe value 1 when default occurs and 0 otherwise, over the 1-year horizon.From the standard def<strong>in</strong>ition of correlation between random variables, onehas the follow<strong>in</strong>g relation for default correlation between the obligors i andk, which is denoted ik: ik E(I [ i 1]I [k 1]) E(I [i 1])E(I [k 1])2Var(I [i 1]) Var(I [k 1])(6.10)


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 99Because the default <strong>in</strong>dicator i is a Bernoulli random variable, one has thefollow<strong>in</strong>g properties:E(I [i 1]) PD i prob( i 1)Var(I [i 1]) 2 PD i PD i (1 PD i )E(I [i 1]I [k 1]) prob( i 1, k 1)(6.11)(6.12)(6.13)Based on these relations, the default correlation between two obligors simplifiesto ik prob( i 1, k 1) PD i PD k2PD i (1 PD i ) PD k (1 PD k )(6.14)Knowledge of the probability of jo<strong>in</strong>t default between obligors allows us tocompute the default correlation us<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.14). Before I discuss variousapproaches that can be used to do this, I first establish the relationshipbetween default correlation and loss correlation when credit risk is estimatedunder the default mode.Relationship to Loss CorrelationThe relationship between default correlation and loss correlation derivedhere is only applicable to the case where the credit loss is estimated underthe default mode. From Chapter 5, the loss variable under the default modefor a nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure NE i is given by/ i NE i I [i 1] (P dirty,i i )(6.15)Under the assumption that default rate and recovery rate processes are <strong>in</strong>dependent,one can derive the follow<strong>in</strong>g relation for the term E(/ i / k):E(/ i/ k) NE i NE k E(I [i 1]I [k 1]) E[(P dirty,i ° i ) (P dirty,k ° k )](6.16)If one makes the further simplify<strong>in</strong>g assumption that the recovery ratesbetween the ith and the kth issuer are <strong>in</strong>dependent, then one obta<strong>in</strong>s the follow<strong>in</strong>grelation:E(/ i/ k) NE i NE k E(I [i 1]I [k 1]) LD i LD k(6.17)


100 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSMak<strong>in</strong>g use of equations (6.10) and (6.12), one can rewrite equation (6.17)as follows:E(/ i/ k) NE i NE k ( PDi PDk ik PD i PD k ) LD i LD k(6.18)Incorporat<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.18) <strong>in</strong>to (6.5) and simplify<strong>in</strong>g gives the follow<strong>in</strong>grelation between loss correlation and default correlation when i k: / ik NE i NE k PDi PDk LD i LD kUL i UL k ik(6.19)Under the assumption that recovery rates for bonds issued by two differentobligors are <strong>in</strong>dependent, equation (6.19) <strong>in</strong>dicates that loss correlation islower than default correlation. In the general case, loss correlation can beeither lower or higher than default correlation depend<strong>in</strong>g on the level ofcorrelation between recovery rates for different obligors. The assumption / ik ik implicitly postulates that recovery rates for different obligors arepositively correlated as follows: r ik ik (UL% i UL% k PDi PDk LD i LD k ) RRi RRk ( ik PDi PDk PD i PD k )(6.20)In equation (6.20), the variable UL% is the unexpected loss as a percentageof exposure, which is given by UL% UL/NE.Estimat<strong>in</strong>g Default CorrelationI mentioned that estimation of the loss correlation between obligors is usuallydone through <strong>in</strong>direct methods. This is also true <strong>in</strong> the case of defaultcorrelation. Because knowledge of default correlation allows one to computeloss correlation and therefore unexpected portfolio loss, I focus onhow default correlation can be estimated. The standard technique for estimat<strong>in</strong>gdefault correlation is based on the latent variable approach. In suchan approach, default of an obligor is assumed to occur if a latent variablethat is considered to play a role <strong>in</strong> the firm’s default falls below a certa<strong>in</strong>threshold value. Correlation between the latent variables of different obligorsis then used to <strong>in</strong>fer the default correlation between obligors.The latent variable that is used <strong>in</strong> practice is the asset returns of theobligor. The motivation for us<strong>in</strong>g asset return as the latent variable is that <strong>in</strong>Merton’s model, a firm’s default is driven by changes <strong>in</strong> its asset value. As aresult, the correlation between the asset returns of two obligors can be usedto compute the default correlation between them. In practice, one uses thecorrelation between asset returns for two obligors to estimate the probability


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 101of their jo<strong>in</strong>t default, which is given by prob( i 1, k 1). Us<strong>in</strong>g this<strong>in</strong>formation, one can compute the default correlation between the obligorsi and k us<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.14).To illustrate the <strong>in</strong>tuition beh<strong>in</strong>d the latent variable approach, recallMerton’s structural model for default. The basic premise of Merton’sdefault model, as discussed <strong>in</strong> Chapter 5, is that when the asset value ofthe firm falls below outstand<strong>in</strong>g liabilities, the firm will default. In thisframework, the jo<strong>in</strong>t probability of two firms default<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong>time period is simply the likelihood of both firms’ asset values fall<strong>in</strong>gbelow their outstand<strong>in</strong>g liabilities. The jo<strong>in</strong>t probability of both firmsdefault<strong>in</strong>g can be computed if one knows the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of assetreturns.At this po<strong>in</strong>t it is useful once aga<strong>in</strong> to recall the discussion <strong>in</strong> Chapter5. Specifically, I showed that under the assumption that asset returns arenormally distributed, it is possible to derive a relationship between theprobability of default and the default threshold. This threshold, denoted D ifor the ith obligor, is obligor specific and depends on asset volatility, leverage,and the outstand<strong>in</strong>g liabilities of the firm. The relationship betweendefault threshold and the obligor’s probability of default is given byDPD i 1 iexp(0.5z 2 )dz22q(6.21)Estimat<strong>in</strong>g the probability of jo<strong>in</strong>t defaults between two firms requiresmak<strong>in</strong>g an assumption regard<strong>in</strong>g the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns. Ifone makes the simplify<strong>in</strong>g assumption that the asset returns are jo<strong>in</strong>tly normaland the asset return correlation between the ith and the kth obligor is, then the jo<strong>in</strong>t probability of default of the two obligors is given by ik1prob( i 1, k 1) 221( ik) 2D i D kq qexp ° x2 2 ikxy y 2¢ dxdy2[1 ( ik) 2 ](6.22)The <strong>in</strong>tegral limits D i and D k can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.21) if oneknows the probability of default of the obligors. Knowledge of the jo<strong>in</strong>tprobability of default for two obligors then allows computation of thedefault correlation between the obligors us<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.14).Remarks The analysis presented so far <strong>in</strong> this chapter <strong>in</strong>dicates that there is aconsiderable degree of subjectivity <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the quantification of portfolio


102 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOScredit risk. First, loss correlations that are required to compute unexpectedportfolio loss need to be estimated us<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>direct approach. If one usesdefault correlation to <strong>in</strong>fer loss correlation, one needs to make furtherassumptions regard<strong>in</strong>g the correlation between recovery rates of differentobligors. Because default correlations themselves are difficult to estimatedirectly, one needs to identify latent variables that <strong>in</strong>fluence defaults.Dependence between latent variables can then be transformed <strong>in</strong>to dependencebetween default events.Asset returns were identified as a potential candidate for the latent variable.Because the marg<strong>in</strong>al distribution of asset returns is assumed to benormal, I took this a step further and claimed that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution ofasset returns between obligors can be modeled as be<strong>in</strong>g normal. In general,if the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution between two random variables is normal, then it canbe shown that the marg<strong>in</strong>al distribution of the two random variables is alsonormal. However, the converse is not generally true. That is, if the marg<strong>in</strong>aldistribution of two random variables is normal, the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution ofthese two random variables may not be bivariate normal. The assumptionthat the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns of obligors <strong>in</strong> the bond portfoliois multivariate normal can result <strong>in</strong> underestimat<strong>in</strong>g the probability of jo<strong>in</strong>tdefaults.Further simplifications are required <strong>in</strong> estimat<strong>in</strong>g asset return correlationsbecause asset returns are not directly observable. In practice, factormodels are used to estimate asset correlation between obligors and this isdiscussed <strong>in</strong> the next section. From the practitioner’s po<strong>in</strong>t of view, it canbe seen that the mechanics <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the process of quantify<strong>in</strong>g portfoliocredit risk is susceptible to considerable model risk.Exist<strong>in</strong>g empirical results suggest that most factors that are determ<strong>in</strong>antsof default probabilities are positively correlated. 1 This <strong>in</strong>cludes assetvalues, asset volatilities, and debt-to-equity ratios. As a consequence,default correlations across firms are also positively correlated. Default correlationstend to have a time-vary<strong>in</strong>g component and are high dur<strong>in</strong>g periodsof economic downturn.DEFAULT MODE: TWO-BOND PORTFOLIOI now present a numerical example compris<strong>in</strong>g a two-bond portfolio toillustrate the various concepts presented so far <strong>in</strong> this chapter. Us<strong>in</strong>g thisexample, I po<strong>in</strong>t out the differences between different correlation measuresand the implications for portfolio credit risk under the default mode whendifferent assumptions are made. The bond-level details of the example portfolioconsidered are given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.1. I assume that the asset returncorrelation between the issuers is 30 percent.


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 103EXHIBIT 6.1<strong>Bond</strong> Level Details of Example ConsideredDescription <strong>Bond</strong> 1 <strong>Bond</strong> 2<strong>Bond</strong> issuer Oracle Corp Alliance CapitalIssuer rat<strong>in</strong>g grade A3 A2Settlement date 24 April 2002 24 April 2002<strong>Bond</strong> maturity date 15 February 2007 15 August 2006Coupon rate (%) 6.91 5.625Dirty price for $1 nom<strong>in</strong>al 1.0533 1.0029Nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure ($) 1,000,000 1,000,000PD (historical) (bp) 10 8KMV’s EDF (bp) 58 158Mean recovery rate (%) 47 47Volatility of RR (%) 25 25Depend<strong>in</strong>g on whether the historical PD or KMV’s EDF is used <strong>in</strong> the calculations,the risk measures of <strong>in</strong>terest can be quite different. This is evidenton exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g numerical results:Us<strong>in</strong>g Historical PD:Jo<strong>in</strong>t default probability prob( i 1, k 1) 1.2505 10 5 .Default correlation Loss correlation / ik 0.01301.ik when recovery rates between issuers are <strong>in</strong>dependent is0.0109.Recovery rate correlation r ik when the assumption / ik ik is made is0.9401.Expected portfolio loss EL P $1,010.Unexpected portfolio loss UL P us<strong>in</strong>g loss correlation is $26,205.Unexpected portfolio loss UL P us<strong>in</strong>g default correlation is $26,233.Us<strong>in</strong>g KMV’s EDF:Jo<strong>in</strong>t default probability prob( i 1, k 1) 5.1096 10 4 .Default correlation Loss correlation / ik 0.04428.ik when recovery rates between issuers are <strong>in</strong>dependent is0.03678.Recovery rate correlation r ik when assumption / ik ik is made is0.83276.Expected portfolio loss EL P $11,803Unexpected portfolio loss UL P us<strong>in</strong>g loss correlation is $89,379Unexpected portfolio loss UL P us<strong>in</strong>g default correlation is $89,676It is useful to note here that if default correlation rather than loss correlationis used to aggregate portfolio unexpected loss, one is mak<strong>in</strong>g the


104 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSassumption that recovery rates between obligors are highly correlated.When us<strong>in</strong>g historical PDs for the issuers <strong>in</strong> this example, the assumptionthat default correlation and loss correlation are the same has the implicationthat recovery rates are almost perfectly correlated. It is also <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>gto note here that there is a 350 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> unexpected loss when theEDF estimates of KMV Corporation are used <strong>in</strong> the calculations <strong>in</strong>stead ofhistorical PDs for the example portfolio.ESTIMATING ASSET RETURN CORRELATIONUnder the assumption that markets are frictionless, and with no taxes andno bankruptcy costs, the value of the firm’s assets is simply the sum of thefirm’s equity and debt as follows:A t S t B t (6.23)Although asset prices are not traded, this equation allows an estimate of theasset value of the firm us<strong>in</strong>g traded equity prices and the present value ofoutstand<strong>in</strong>g debt. Once this is accomplished, estimat<strong>in</strong>g asset return correlationbetween issuers becomes a simple exercise of comput<strong>in</strong>g the historicalcorrelation between the asset return time series of various obligors.From an academic po<strong>in</strong>t of view, this task is fairly straightforward.However, <strong>in</strong> practice, comput<strong>in</strong>g the present value of outstand<strong>in</strong>g liabilitiesis far from be<strong>in</strong>g a simple task. This is because firms have multiple liabilities,and corporate loans, which are part of the liabilities, are not traded. Tocircumvent this problem, practitioners seek to <strong>in</strong>fer the asset return correlationbetween obligors on the basis of observed equity returns. The <strong>in</strong>tuitionbeh<strong>in</strong>d such an approach is l<strong>in</strong>ked to Merton’s structural model forvalu<strong>in</strong>g risky debt. In Merton’s framework, the bondholder can be seen asmak<strong>in</strong>g a loan matur<strong>in</strong>g at time T to f<strong>in</strong>ance the operations of the firm. Therisk faced by the bondholder is the risk that the firm cannot repay the facevalue of the loan at maturity. To hedge this risk, the bondholder can purchasea put option on the asset value of the firm with strike price equal tothe face value of debt and option maturity equal to the term of the loan.Because such a strategy is riskless, the return of this hedged portfolio shouldbe equal to the risk-free rate of <strong>in</strong>terest. If F denotes the face value of thedebt, r the risk-free <strong>in</strong>terest rate, p t the value of the put option, and B t thecurrent value of debt, one has the follow<strong>in</strong>g relation:B t p t Fe rT F t (6.24)Equations (6.23) and (6.24) give the follow<strong>in</strong>g relation:A t S t F t p t (6.25)


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 105Because this relation holds for all t, one obta<strong>in</strong>s the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stantaneousrelationship:dA t dS t dF t dp t (6.26)In general, changes <strong>in</strong> equity prices are closely related to changes <strong>in</strong> optionprices. If this co-movement is exploited, one can approximate the forego<strong>in</strong>grelation as follows:dA t dS t dF t dS t (1 )dS t dF t (6.27)Divid<strong>in</strong>g both sides of equation (6.27) by A t leads to the follow<strong>in</strong>g relation:dA tA t (1 ) S t dS t F t dF tA t S t A t F t(6.28)Equation (6.28) shows the relationship between asset returns, equityreturns, and risk-free bond returns. With w F t A t , equation (6.28) simplifiestor A (1 w) r S w r F (6.29)Equation (6.29) is the familiar relation that is exploited to relate the assetreturn correlation between obligors to the equity return correlation. For<strong>in</strong>stance, the covariance between the asset returns of two obligors i and kus<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.29) can be written ascov(r A i , r A k ) (1 w i ) (1 w k ) cov(r S i , r S k ) (1 w i ) w k cov(r S i , r F k ) w i (1 w k ) cov(r F i , r S k ) w i w k cov(r F i , r F k )(6.30)If it is assumed that w is small and the equity returns and risk-free bondreturns are weakly correlated, this equation can be further simplified asfollows:cov(r i A, r k A) (1 w i ) (1 w k ) cov(r i S, r k S )(6.31)This relationship provides the economic motivation for us<strong>in</strong>g equity returncorrelations to <strong>in</strong>fer the asset return correlation between obligors.Remarks The quantity w F t A t is the leverage ratio of the firm. For firmshav<strong>in</strong>g a relatively low leverage ratio, equity return correlation provides areasonable approximation to asset return correlation. This is because forsuch firms one can make use of the approximate relationship given by equation(6.31). On the other hand, for firms hav<strong>in</strong>g a high leverage ratio, asset


106 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSreturns will be correlated through both equity components and risk-freedebt components. For such firms, the asset return correlation is higher thanthe equity return correlation. To see why this is the case, note that highlyleveraged firms have substantial proportions of long-term debt that are sensitiveto <strong>in</strong>terest rates. For such firms, the ratios w i and w k are large, and r Fikand r F are highly correlated through their sensitivities to <strong>in</strong>terest rates. Asa result, the asset return correlations are higher than their correspond<strong>in</strong>gequity return correlations.Summariz<strong>in</strong>g the above analysis, economic theory suggests that firmswith low leverage ratio have approximately the same levels of asset returnand equity return correlation. On the other hand, highly leveraged firms canhave significantly higher asset return correlation compared to the equityreturn correlation between the firms. A recent empirical study conducted byKMV Corporation demonstrates that this is <strong>in</strong>deed the case. 2 By compar<strong>in</strong>gthe relationship between equity return correlation and asset return correlation,KMV concluded that for firms belong<strong>in</strong>g to the f<strong>in</strong>ancial and utilitiessectors, realized asset return correlation is on average 55 percent higherthan the correspond<strong>in</strong>g equity return correlation. The reason for this differenceis that firms <strong>in</strong> both these sectors are highly leveraged. Industrialfirms, on the other hand, have less leverage. For such firms, equity returncorrelation can serve as a reasonable approximation to asset return correlation.Aga<strong>in</strong> the empirical study of KMV leads to a similar conclusion.The approach outl<strong>in</strong>ed for deriv<strong>in</strong>g asset return correlation is based onthe assumption that the equity of the firm is traded. This is not always thecase. For example, Ford Motor <strong>Credit</strong> has significant outstand<strong>in</strong>g debt, butonly the parent company’s equity is traded. In this case, it is not obvioushow the asset return correlation between such a firm and other debt issuerscan be estimated. Further difficulties can arise with regard to classify<strong>in</strong>g afirm as belong<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>in</strong>dustrial, the utilities, or the f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector. For<strong>in</strong>stance, should Ford Motor <strong>Credit</strong> be grouped under the f<strong>in</strong>ancial sectoror the automotive sector? One can avoid address<strong>in</strong>g these questions directlyif a factor-based model is used to estimate asset return correlation. Thisis taken up <strong>in</strong> the next section.Factor ModelsThe objective of any risk-model<strong>in</strong>g exercise is to be able to use the riskmodel to predict future risk scenarios. To achieve this objective, one needsto f<strong>in</strong>d good forward-look<strong>in</strong>g estimates of the <strong>in</strong>put variables that def<strong>in</strong>e therisk model. One important <strong>in</strong>put variable for the risk model is the assetreturn correlation between obligor pairs. In general, the ability to f<strong>in</strong>d agood forward-look<strong>in</strong>g estimate of asset or equity return correlation betweenobligor pairs is the most difficult part of any risk-model<strong>in</strong>g exercise. This is


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 107because historical data have the effect of magnify<strong>in</strong>g firm-specific eventsthat may not be relevant <strong>in</strong> the future and this can bias correlation estimates.Moreover, a company’s bus<strong>in</strong>ess may change over time throughacquisitions and mergers. In such cases, historical equity or asset returns ofthe company may not reflect the true risks <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> the new bus<strong>in</strong>essstrategy pursued by the company.One can avoid some of these pitfalls by us<strong>in</strong>g a factor model to estimateasset return correlation between different obligors. A factor modelrelates the systematic or nondiversifiable components of the firm’s assetreturns to various common factors such as macroeconomic variables orreturns on prespecified portfolios, which drive the firm’s asset value.Knowledge of the sensitivities to the common factors and the correlationbetween the common factors then allows an estimate of the asset returncorrelation between obligors. In the context of estimat<strong>in</strong>g asset return correlation,the factors that are commonly used <strong>in</strong>clude asset returns of various<strong>in</strong>dustry and country groups and macroeconomic factors. In case thebus<strong>in</strong>ess strategy of a company changes, one can immediately <strong>in</strong>fer theimpact of this change on the asset return correlation between the companyand other firms. This is possible because a change <strong>in</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess strategyresults <strong>in</strong> a change <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry or country factor sensitivities tocommon factors.For most practical applications, one restricts the factor model to be l<strong>in</strong>ear.In its most generic form, such a l<strong>in</strong>ear factor model can be written asmr i a b ik f k e ik1(6.32)In this equation, r i is the asset return of the ith firm, the f k are the commonfactors, the b ik are the sensitivities to the common factors, and e i is the firmspecificor idiosyncratic return. The sensitivity term b ik has the <strong>in</strong>terpretationthat it represents the change <strong>in</strong> the return of the ith firm for a unitchange <strong>in</strong> factor k. The firm-specific component of the return e i has theproperty that it is uncorrelated with each of the factors f k . An additionalkey assumption of the l<strong>in</strong>ear factor model is that the residual return of onefirm is uncorrelated with the residual return of any other firm. This has theimplication that the only sources of correlation among asset returns of firmsare those that arise from their exposures to the common factors and thecovariance among the common factors.Under those assumptions, it is easy to show that the covariancebetween the return of the ith firm and the return of the kth firm iscov(r i , r k ) amk1 a ml1b ik b jl cov(f k , f l ) cov(e i , e k )(6.33)


108 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSThe last term <strong>in</strong> equation (6.33) is zero when i k. Us<strong>in</strong>g the factor model,it is easy to derive the correlation between the asset returns of the ith firmand the kth firm. This is given by ik cov(r i, r k )(6.34) i kwhere(6.35)The forego<strong>in</strong>g factor model concept is exploited by both KMV Corporationand <strong>Credit</strong>Metrics to derive the asset return correlation betweenobligors. The important difference between the two is that KMV uses assetreturns to construct the factor model, whereas <strong>Credit</strong>Metrics’ implementationis based on equity returns. 3For purposes of illustration, I briefly describe the factor model implementationof KMV Corporation for estimat<strong>in</strong>g asset return correlationbetween obligors. 4 Assume a firm’s asset return comprises a component thatis firm specific and another that is nondiversifiable. The nondiversifiablecomponent of asset return can be considered to comprise a component thatis <strong>in</strong>dustry specific and another that is country specific. Further subclassificationof the <strong>in</strong>dustry and country asset returns can be made to <strong>in</strong>crease thegranularity of the asset correlation estimates. The mechanics <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>such a decomposition of asset returns is given as follows:£££Compositefactor § £returnCountryfactorreturnIndustryfactorreturnCountryfactor § £returnGlobal§ £ economic § £effectGlobal§ £ economic § £effect i 2cov(r i , r i )Firm Composite Firmspecific£ asset § £ factor §§ £return return returnIndustryfactor §returnRegionalfactoreffectRegionalfactoreffectSector§ £ factor § £effectSector§ £ factor § £effectCountryspecific§effectIndustryspecific§effectOn the basis of this decomposition, asset return correlations are computedfrom each firm’s composite factor return. In KMV’s global correlation


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 109model, <strong>in</strong>dustry and country <strong>in</strong>dices are produced from a global databaseof market asset values estimated from the traded equity prices together witheach firm’s outstand<strong>in</strong>g liabilities. These <strong>in</strong>dices are then used to create acomposite factor <strong>in</strong>dex for each firm depend<strong>in</strong>g on its country and <strong>in</strong>dustryclassification.Approximate Asset Return CorrelationsThe forego<strong>in</strong>g method of comput<strong>in</strong>g asset return correlations betweenobligors us<strong>in</strong>g factor models is fairly complex. When manag<strong>in</strong>g large corporatebond portfolios, one may wish to use a data vendor rather than estimateasset return correlations <strong>in</strong>-house. However, when the costs <strong>in</strong>volvedare high relative to the size of the portfolio be<strong>in</strong>g managed, one may wishto f<strong>in</strong>d reasonable approximations to the asset return correlation. I outl<strong>in</strong>ea simple procedure that can be used to compute approximate asset returncorrelation between obligors.Earlier <strong>in</strong> this chapter, I remarked that a study conducted by KMV Corporationsuggested that average equity return correlations are 55 percentlower than average asset return correlations for f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions andutilities. For <strong>in</strong>dustrial corporates, on the other hand, equity return correlationsand asset return correlations are approximately the same. The medianequity correlations <strong>in</strong> the KMV study are reported to be 20 percent forf<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions, 12 percent for utilities, and 18 percent for large <strong>in</strong>dustrialcorporates. The median asset return correlations, on the other hand,are approximately 34 percent for f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions, 20 percent for utilities,and 18 percent for <strong>in</strong>dustrials. Mak<strong>in</strong>g use of this <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> conjunctionwith equation (6.30), it is possible to derive the approximate leverageratio w for the different <strong>in</strong>dustry group<strong>in</strong>gs. Specifically, if one assumesthat the leverage ratio is the same across each <strong>in</strong>dustry sector and that theoutstand<strong>in</strong>g debt has the same maturity for all firms, one can derive the follow<strong>in</strong>gequation: ik (1 w i )(1 w k ) e ik w i w k(6.36)In deriv<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.36), we have made the assumption that all returns<strong>in</strong> equation (6.30) are standardized normal variables. The variables <strong>in</strong> equation(6.36) are the follow<strong>in</strong>g:w i Leverage ratio for the ith <strong>in</strong>dustry sector. e ik Equity return correlation between the ith and the kth <strong>in</strong>dustrysectors. ik Asset return correlation between the ith and the kth <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors.


110 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSUs<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.36) and the reported values for equity and asset returncorrelations, we obta<strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g leverage ratios for the various <strong>in</strong>dustrysectors:w F<strong>in</strong>ancial 55 percentw Utility 40 percentw Industrial 30 percentTo compute approximate asset return correlations between the different<strong>in</strong>dustry sectors, assume that the median equity return correlation reported forfirms <strong>in</strong> a given sector can be used. In particular, assume that the equity returncorrelation between the sectors takes the lower value of the equity return correlationfor given sectors. For example, the equity return correlation betweenthe f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector and the utilities sector is taken to be 12 percent. Given theleverage ratios for each sector and the equity return correlations between thesectors, it is fairly straightforward to compute the asset return correlationus<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.36). The asset return correlations obta<strong>in</strong>ed from such anexercise for the three major <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors are given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.2.It is possible to <strong>in</strong>crease the granularity of the these estimates when comput<strong>in</strong>gthe asset return correlation between two obligors. For <strong>in</strong>stance,obligors could be classified <strong>in</strong> terms of the actual <strong>in</strong>dustry they belong towith<strong>in</strong> the sector. Under such a classification, one can assume that the assetreturn correlation between two obligors <strong>in</strong> the same <strong>in</strong>dustry group is higherthan the value at the sector level. Furthermore, one could also <strong>in</strong>corporatethe empirical evidence that the asset return correlations between lower ratedfirms are higher. Possible subclassifications with<strong>in</strong> the sectors are as follows:Industrial Sector:Consumer noncyclical (CNC)Consumer cyclical (CCL)Basic <strong>in</strong>dustries and chemicals (BAC)Communication and technology (COT)Energy (ENE)Transportation (TRA)EXHIBIT 6.2Approximate Asset Return Correlations for Major Industry SectorsF<strong>in</strong>ancials (%) Utilities (%) Industrials (%)F<strong>in</strong>ancials 34 25 22Utilities 25 20 17Industrials 22 17 18


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 111F<strong>in</strong>ancial Sector:Banks (BNK)Brokerage (BRO)F<strong>in</strong>ancial services (FIN)Insurance and reits (INR)Utilities Sector:Utilities (UTL)The total asset return correlation between two obligors can then beassumed to consist of three components: ik ik (sector) ik (<strong>in</strong>dustry) ik (rat<strong>in</strong>g)(6.37)A suggested value for the component of the asset return correlation aris<strong>in</strong>gfrom the <strong>in</strong>dustry and rat<strong>in</strong>g categories is 10% of the sector component. Forthe component of the asset return correlation aris<strong>in</strong>g from rat<strong>in</strong>gs, one considersan <strong>in</strong>creased contribution only if both firms are rated below A3. Incorporat<strong>in</strong>gthese values <strong>in</strong>to equation (6.37) results <strong>in</strong> the follow<strong>in</strong>g equation,which captures the total asset return correlation between two obligors: ik ik,S 0.10 ik,S (if <strong>in</strong>dustry i <strong>in</strong>dustry k ) 0.10 ik,S (if rat<strong>in</strong>g i and rat<strong>in</strong>g k A3)(6.38) ik, SIn this equation, is the component of the asset return correlation fromthe sector exposure, which is given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.2.CREDIT RISK UNDER MIGRATION MODEI have discussed how loss correlation between obligor pairs can be estimatedunder the default mode. I showed how loss correlation is related todefault correlation under the default mode and further established the l<strong>in</strong>kbetween asset return correlation and default correlation. When portfoliocredit risk is computed <strong>in</strong> the migration mode, the estimate of loss correlationbetween obligor pairs is different. Because loss correlation is difficultto estimate directly, asset return correlations are aga<strong>in</strong> used to derive theloss correlation between obligors under the migration mode. In this section,I <strong>in</strong>dicate how loss correlation under the migration mode can be determ<strong>in</strong>edus<strong>in</strong>g asset return correlation <strong>in</strong>formation.Earlier <strong>in</strong> this chapter I showed that to determ<strong>in</strong>e the loss correlationbetween two obligors, one has to compute the term E(/ 1/ 2). This quantity


112 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSis the expected value of the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of credit loss of a two-obligorportfolio. Under the migration mode, any obligor can migrate to one of 18states (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the current state). In this model, state 1 corresponds to anAaa rat<strong>in</strong>g and state 18 corresponds to the default state. Clearly, the jo<strong>in</strong>tdistribution for a two-obligor portfolio <strong>in</strong> this framework is a discrete distributionthat can take 324 states (18 18). If the probability of occupy<strong>in</strong>geach of these states and the credit loss <strong>in</strong> each state is known, the expectedvalue of the jo<strong>in</strong>t credit loss can be computed.Comput<strong>in</strong>g the probabilities associated with each of the states <strong>in</strong> thejo<strong>in</strong>t distribution requires model<strong>in</strong>g correlated rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations. Becauseasset returns of a firm <strong>in</strong>fluence rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations, the asset return correlationbetween obligors can be used to compute the probability of occupy<strong>in</strong>gdifferent states <strong>in</strong> the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution. Essentially the approach to estimat<strong>in</strong>gthe probabilities requires extend<strong>in</strong>g Merton’s framework to <strong>in</strong>cluderat<strong>in</strong>g migrations. The generalization <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g thresholds for rat<strong>in</strong>gmigrations <strong>in</strong> addition to the default threshold to trigger credit eventsus<strong>in</strong>g the firm’s asset returns. This makes it possible to build a l<strong>in</strong>k betweenthe firm’s underly<strong>in</strong>g value and its credit rat<strong>in</strong>g to determ<strong>in</strong>e the jo<strong>in</strong>t probabilitiesof the two obligors <strong>in</strong> different states.For purpose of illustration, consider an obligor that has a current creditrat<strong>in</strong>g of A1. Let p A1,Aaa denote the probability of transition<strong>in</strong>g to thecredit rat<strong>in</strong>g Aaa. Under the assumption that the asset returns of the obligoris normally distributed, the credit event that signals the obligor rat<strong>in</strong>gmigration from A1 to Aaa occurs when the standardized asset returns of theobligor exceeds the threshold z A1,Aaa . This threshold can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed bysolv<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tegral equation:qP A1,Aaa 1 exp(0.5x 2 )dx22z A1,Aaa(6.39)A rat<strong>in</strong>g transition of this obligor from A1 to Aa1 occurs if the asset returnfalls between the thresholds z A1,Aaa and z A1,Aa1 . The threshold z A1,Aa1 can bedeterm<strong>in</strong>ed by solv<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tegral equation:zP A1,Aa1 1A1,Aaa exp(0.5x 2 )dx22z A1,Aa1(6.40)One can extend this sequential rule to determ<strong>in</strong>e the thresholds for migrat<strong>in</strong>gto other rat<strong>in</strong>g grades. Note that these z-thresholds are a function of thecurrent credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the obligor. Exhibit 6.3 shows the z-thresholds computedus<strong>in</strong>g the normalized rat<strong>in</strong>g transition probabilities given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit5.5 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 5.


113Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa DefAaa 1.229 1.666 2.109 2.239 2.567 2.849 3.280 3.280 3.280 3.280 3.719 3.719 3.719 3.719 3.719 3.719 3.719 1000Aa1 1.936 0.910 1.284 1.867 2.464 2.694 2.746 3.052 3.052 3.052 3.540 3.540 3.540 3.540 3.540 3.540 3.540 1000Aa2 2.439 1.776 1.023 1.515 1.984 2.348 2.712 2.935 2.935 2.935 2.935 2.935 3.051 3.432 3.432 3.432 3.432 1000Aa3 3.143 2.446 1.724 1.067 1.646 2.119 2.403 2.534 2.703 2.918 2.918 3.002 3.353 3.353 3.353 3.353 3.353 1000A1 3.421 2.977 2.423 1.512 1.145 1.634 2.031 2.227 2.320 2.373 2.571 2.810 2.886 3.193 3.239 3.239 3.239 1000A2 3.279 3.049 2.638 2.251 1.492 1.152 1.646 2.054 2.269 2.429 2.600 2.686 2.811 2.855 2.983 3.058 3.156 1000A3 3.277 2.953 2.863 2.611 2.052 1.244 1.084 1.484 1.872 2.154 2.329 2.412 2.535 2.854 2.942 3.060 3.090 1000Baa1 3.142 3.076 2.819 2.628 2.489 1.814 1.199 1.089 1.548 1.914 2.122 2.254 2.390 2.787 2.925 2.966 3.011 1000Baa2 3.179 2.913 2.742 2.586 2.476 2.149 1.603 1.140 1.179 1.693 1.919 2.014 2.166 2.323 2.552 2.792 2.834 1000Baa3 3.415 3.415 3.221 2.993 2.717 2.351 2.138 1.640 1.038 1.092 1.480 1.729 2.019 2.220 2.329 2.495 2.605 1000Ba1 3.131 3.131 3.131 3.036 2.688 2.583 2.251 2.047 1.623 1.099 1.076 1.335 1.658 1.793 2.001 2.316 2.473 1000Ba2 1000 1000 1000 3.406 3.167 2.818 2.665 2.423 2.160 1.743 1.115 0.978 1.305 1.422 1.789 2.141 2.315 1000Ba3 1000 3.518 3.518 3.518 3.215 2.822 2.633 2.507 2.370 2.135 1.687 1.278 0.932 1.159 1.497 1.827 1.967 1000B1 3.522 3.522 3.522 3.522 3.136 2.908 2.704 2.638 2.471 2.328 2.185 1.735 1.268 0.906 1.142 1.566 1.754 1000B2 1000 1000 3.229 3.185 2.900 2.900 2.796 2.624 2.537 2.435 2.310 1.922 1.573 1.188 0.678 1.117 1.318 1000B3 1000 1000 3.212 3.212 3.129 3.007 2.882 2.728 2.612 2.473 2.379 2.241 1.954 1.480 1.246 0.798 1.093 1000Caa 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 2.552 2.301 2.100 2.100 1.838 1.610 1.496 1.285 0.536 1000Def 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000EXHIBIT 6.3 z-Thresholds for Various Rat<strong>in</strong>g Grades


114 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSComput<strong>in</strong>g Jo<strong>in</strong>t Migration ProbabilitiesHav<strong>in</strong>g determ<strong>in</strong>ed the various thresholds for credit migration of anyobligor, one can compute the jo<strong>in</strong>t migration probabilities of two obligors.Comput<strong>in</strong>g these jo<strong>in</strong>t migration probabilities, however, requires knowledgeof the jo<strong>in</strong>t probability distribution of the asset returns of the twoobligors and the correlation between them. Standard practice is to modelthe jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution to be bivariate normal. Once aga<strong>in</strong>, for purpose ofillustration, let the current credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of obligor 1 be A1 and the creditrat<strong>in</strong>g of obligor 2 be A3. Let denote the asset return correlationbetween the two obligors. The jo<strong>in</strong>t probability that obligor 1 migratesto a B2 rat<strong>in</strong>g and obligor 2 migrates to an Aaa rat<strong>in</strong>g is given by the follow<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>tegral equation:1h B2,Aaa 221 2z A1,B1z A1,B2q exp ° x2 2xy y 2¢ dxdy2(1 2 )z A3,Aaa(6.41)In equation (6.41), z A1,B1 is the threshold correspond<strong>in</strong>g to the row A1 andcolumn B1 <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.3. The other z-thresholds can be similarly determ<strong>in</strong>edfrom Exhibit 6.3. Follow<strong>in</strong>g this approach, it is fairly straightforwardto compute the jo<strong>in</strong>t migration probabilities h ik to any of 324 discretestates for a two-obligor portfolio. The probability h 64 , for <strong>in</strong>stance, denotesthe jo<strong>in</strong>t probability that after 1 year obligor 1 has an A2 rat<strong>in</strong>g and obligor2 has an Aa3 rat<strong>in</strong>g.Comput<strong>in</strong>g Jo<strong>in</strong>t <strong>Credit</strong> LossTo compute the expected value of the jo<strong>in</strong>t loss distribution, one needs todeterm<strong>in</strong>e the credit loss associated with each state of the discrete jo<strong>in</strong>t probabilitydistribution. Assume that the <strong>in</strong>itial credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of obligor 1 is u andthat of obligor 2 is v. After 1 year, let the credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs of these two obligorsbe i and k, respectively. The jo<strong>in</strong>t credit loss as a result of the rat<strong>in</strong>g migrationof obligor 1 to state i and that of obligor 2 to state k is given byg ik NE 1 NE 2 ¢P ui,1 ¢P vk,2(6.42)In equation (6.42), P ui,1 is the credit loss when obligor 1 migrates fromgrade u to grade i. This can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g equation (5.32) given <strong>in</strong>Chapter 5. One can similarly determ<strong>in</strong>e the credit loss result<strong>in</strong>g from obligor2 migrat<strong>in</strong>g from grade v to grade k, which is given by P vk,2 . If theobligor migrates to the default state, then the correspond<strong>in</strong>g credit loss is


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 115equal to loss on default LD. I make the assumption that the loss on defaultof each obligor is <strong>in</strong>dependent of that of the other so that the expected valueof jo<strong>in</strong>t credit loss when both obligors default is simply the product of the<strong>in</strong>dividual losses at default of the obligors.Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong>Once the jo<strong>in</strong>t probabilities of be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each of the states and the correspond<strong>in</strong>gcredit losses have been determ<strong>in</strong>ed, it is fairly simple to computethe expected value of the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of credit loss. This isgiven byE(/ 1/ 2) a18i1 a 18k1h ik g ik(6.43)One now has all the quantities that are required to compute the loss correlationbetween the two obligors under the migration mode us<strong>in</strong>g equation(6.5). Once the loss correlation between the obligors is computed, theunexpected loss for a two-bond portfolio can be computed us<strong>in</strong>g equation(6.7). For a general portfolio hav<strong>in</strong>g n bonds, the loss correlation under themigration mode can be computed follow<strong>in</strong>g the forego<strong>in</strong>g approach for anyobligor pair. Lett<strong>in</strong>g EL i and UL i denote, respectively, the expected loss andunexpected loss of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio under the migration mode,one can compute the expected and unexpected loss of the portfolio us<strong>in</strong>gequations (6.8) and (6.9).Migration Mode: Two-<strong>Bond</strong> PortfolioI now consider the two-bond portfolio given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.1 and compute theportfolio credit risk under the migration mode. As a first step, one needs tocompute the jo<strong>in</strong>t rat<strong>in</strong>g migration probabilities <strong>in</strong> each of the 324 statesand the correspond<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>t credit losses to determ<strong>in</strong>e the loss correlation.The jo<strong>in</strong>t rat<strong>in</strong>g migration probabilities and jo<strong>in</strong>t credit loss <strong>in</strong> each of the324 states of the discrete probability distribution for the two-bond portfolioare given <strong>in</strong> Exhibits 6.4 and 6.5, respectively.The various credit risk parameters of <strong>in</strong>terest for this two-bond portfolioare as follows:The loss correlation / ik under the migration mode is 0.06334.The expected portfolio loss EL P under the migration mode is $4,740.The unexpected portfolio loss UL P under the migration mode $31,610.(text cont<strong>in</strong>ued on page 118)


116Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa-C DefAaa 0.0005 0.0007 0.0003 0.0012 0.0051 0.0143 0.0293 0.0004 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa1 0.0005 0.0007 0.0003 0.0011 0.0052 0.0159 0.0380 0.0007 0.0002 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa2 0.0016 0.0025 0.0011 0.0045 0.0213 0.0708 0.1939 0.0044 0.0016 0.0004 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa3 0.0030 0.0048 0.0022 0.0092 0.0466 0.1693 0.5438 0.0150 0.0057 0.0016 0.0005 0.0001 0.0002 0.0002 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000A1 0.0115 0.0204 0.0096 0.0418 0.2304 0.9631 4.0379 0.1546 0.0635 0.0191 0.0060 0.0019 0.0020 0.0026 0.0003 0.0003 0.0001 0.0004A2 0.0348 0.0743 0.0381 0.1790 1.2059 7.0429 61.9039 5.3813 2.8154 1.0554 0.3877 0.1333 0.1518 0.2200 0.0322 0.0313 0.0062 0.0555A3 0.0004 0.0012 0.0007 0.0035 0.0312 0.2734 5.3686 0.8220 0.5054 0.2172 0.0874 0.0316 0.0374 0.0584 0.0093 0.0094 0.0019 0.0188Baa1 0.0001 0.0003 0.0002 0.0009 0.0083 0.0809 2.0409 0.3700 0.2410 0.1089 0.0454 0.0168 0.0201 0.0324 0.0053 0.0054 0.0011 0.0116Baa2 0.0000 0.0001 0.0000 0.0002 0.0017 0.0179 0.5456 0.1113 0.0756 0.0354 0.0151 0.0057 0.0069 0.0113 0.0019 0.0020 0.0004 0.0044Baa3 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0007 0.0076 0.2578 0.0562 0.0391 0.0187 0.0081 0.0031 0.0037 0.0062 0.0011 0.0011 0.0002 0.0025Ba1 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0004 0.0048 0.1797 0.0415 0.0295 0.0144 0.0063 0.0024 0.0029 0.0050 0.0009 0.0009 0.0002 0.0021Ba2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0016 0.0631 0.0152 0.0110 0.0055 0.0024 0.0009 0.0011 0.0019 0.0003 0.0004 0.0001 0.0008Ba3 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0016 0.0679 0.0170 0.0124 0.0062 0.0028 0.0011 0.0013 0.0023 0.0004 0.0004 0.0001 0.0010B1 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0004 0.0185 0.0048 0.0035 0.0018 0.0008 0.0003 0.0004 0.0007 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0003B2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0009 0.0416 0.0110 0.0082 0.0042 0.0019 0.0007 0.0009 0.0016 0.0003 0.0003 0.0001 0.0007B3 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0176 0.0048 0.0037 0.0019 0.0009 0.0003 0.0004 0.0007 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0003Caa–C 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0174 0.0049 0.0037 0.0020 0.0009 0.0003 0.0004 0.0008 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0004Def 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0007 0.0411 0.0128 0.0102 0.0055 0.0026 0.0010 0.0013 0.0024 0.0004 0.0005 0.0001 0.0013EXHIBIT 6.4 Jo<strong>in</strong>t Rat<strong>in</strong>g Migration Probabilities for 30% Asset Return Correlation


Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa–C DefAaa 0.0011 0.0009 0.0007 0.0006 0.0004 0.0002 0.0000 0.0003 0.0006 0.0009 0.0015 0.0020 0.0026 0.0036 0.0046 0.0056 0.0068 0.0167Aa1 0.0009 0.0007 0.0006 0.0004 0.0003 0.0002 0.0000 0.0002 0.0005 0.0007 0.0012 0.0016 0.0021 0.0029 0.0037 0.0044 0.0055 0.0133Aa2 0.0007 0.0006 0.0004 0.0003 0.0002 0.0001 0.0000 0.0002 0.0004 0.0005 0.0009 0.0012 0.0015 0.0022 0.0028 0.0033 0.0041 0.0100Aa3 0.0004 0.0004 0.0003 0.0002 0.0002 0.0001 0.0000 0.0001 0.0002 0.0004 0.0006 0.0008 0.0010 0.0014 0.0018 0.0022 0.0027 0.0066A1 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0001 0.0002 0.0003 0.0004 0.0005 0.0007 0.0009 0.0011 0.0014 0.0033A2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000A3 0.0002 0.0002 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0001 0.0002 0.0003 0.0004 0.0005 0.0007 0.0009 0.0011 0.0013 0.0033Baa1 0.0006 0.0005 0.0004 0.0003 0.0002 0.0001 0.0000 0.0002 0.0003 0.0005 0.0008 0.0011 0.0013 0.0019 0.0024 0.0029 0.0036 0.0087Baa2 0.0009 0.0008 0.0006 0.0005 0.0003 0.0002 0.0000 0.0003 0.0005 0.0008 0.0012 0.0017 0.0022 0.0031 0.0039 0.0047 0.0057 0.0140Baa3 0.0013 0.0011 0.0009 0.0006 0.0004 0.0002 0.0000 0.0004 0.0007 0.0010 0.0017 0.0024 0.0030 0.0042 0.0053 0.0064 0.0079 0.0193Ba1 0.0020 0.0017 0.0013 0.0010 0.0007 0.0003 0.0000 0.0005 0.0011 0.0016 0.0026 0.0036 0.0046 0.0065 0.0082 0.0099 0.0121 0.0297Ba2 0.0027 0.0022 0.0018 0.0013 0.0009 0.0004 0.0000 0.0007 0.0014 0.0021 0.0035 0.0048 0.0062 0.0087 0.0110 0.0132 0.0163 0.0398Ba3 0.0033 0.0028 0.0022 0.0016 0.0011 0.0005 0.0000 0.0009 0.0018 0.0027 0.0044 0.0061 0.0077 0.0108 0.0137 0.0165 0.0203 0.0497B1 0.0046 0.0038 0.0030 0.0023 0.0015 0.0008 0.0000 0.0012 0.0025 0.0037 0.0061 0.0084 0.0106 0.0149 0.0190 0.0228 0.0281 0.0687B2 0.0058 0.0048 0.0038 0.0029 0.0019 0.0010 0.0000 0.0016 0.0031 0.0046 0.0076 0.0106 0.0134 0.0189 0.0240 0.0288 0.0355 0.0867B3 0.0069 0.0058 0.0046 0.0034 0.0023 0.0011 0.0000 0.0019 0.0037 0.0056 0.0091 0.0126 0.0160 0.0226 0.0287 0.0345 0.0425 0.1038Caa–C 0.0085 0.0071 0.0056 0.0042 0.0028 0.0014 0.0000 0.0023 0.0046 0.0068 0.0112 0.0155 0.0197 0.0277 0.0353 0.0424 0.0522 0.1275Def 0.0208 0.0173 0.0138 0.0103 0.0068 0.0034 0.0000 0.0056 0.0112 0.0166 0.0274 0.0378 0.0480 0.0676 0.0860 0.1033 0.1272 0.3108EXHIBIT 6.5 Jo<strong>in</strong>t <strong>Credit</strong> Loss Distribution <strong>in</strong> Million USD


118 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSNote that under the migration mode, both expected and unexpectedportfolio losses of the two-bond portfolio are higher than under thedefault mode us<strong>in</strong>g historical default probabilities. The loss correlationunder the migration mode is also significantly higher than under thedefault mode.NUMERICAL EXAMPLEI now consider a more general portfolio to illustrate the portfolio credit riskconcepts covered <strong>in</strong> this chapter. The specific portfolio comprises 23 bondswith issuer credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs vary<strong>in</strong>g from A1 to Ba3. It is assumed that thenom<strong>in</strong>al exposure is $20 million <strong>in</strong> each bond. The traded prices for thesebonds were captured as of 24 April 2002. The details of <strong>in</strong>dividual bondsheld <strong>in</strong> the portfolio are given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.6. All bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio arenoncallable and are treated as senior unsecured debt. The recovery rates forthe bonds are assumed to be 47 percent of face value and the standard deviationof recovery rates to be 25 percent.To compute the portfolio credit loss, one requires values for assetreturn correlation between the issuers <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. I consider two cases:one where the asset return correlation is assumed to be 30 percent betweenevery issuer pair and the other where the asset return correlation is computedon the basis of equation (6.38). The asset return correlation betweenthe issuers for this portfolio is given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.7.In the context of bond portfolio management, it is customary to reportvarious risk quantities relative to the current mark-to-market value of theportfolio. In accordance with this practice, I <strong>in</strong>troduce two additional riskterms, percentage portfolio expected loss (%EL P ) and percentage portfoliounexpected loss (%UL P ). If M P denotes the mark-to-market value of theportfolio, the two additional risk terms areand%EL P EL PM P%UL P UL PM P(6.44)(6.45)The portfolio credit risk quantities of <strong>in</strong>terest under the default mode aregiven <strong>in</strong> Exhibits 6.8 and 6.9. Exhibits 6.10 gives the portfolio credit riskquantities of <strong>in</strong>terest under the migration mode.


119Issuer Nom<strong>in</strong>al Dirty KMV’sS. No. Issuer Ticker Industry Rat<strong>in</strong>g USD mn Price Maturity Coupon (%) EDF (bp)1 Health Care Reit HCN INR Ba1 20.0 99.91 15 Aug 07 7.500 32 Hilton Hotels HLT CCL Ba1 20.0 104.13 15 May 08 7.625 293 Apple Computer AAPL COT Ba2 20.0 100.97 15 Feb 04 6.500 1444 Delta Air L<strong>in</strong>es DAL TRA Ba3 20.0 99.42 15 Dec 09 7.900 1475 Alcoa Inc AA BAC A1 20.0 105.24 01 Jun 06 5.875 216 ABN Amro Bank AAB BNK Aa3 20.0 109.18 31 May 05 7.250 107 Abbey Natl Plc ABBEY BNK Aa3 20.0 108.43 17 Nov 05 6.690 338 Alliance Capital AC FIN A2 20.0 100.29 15 Aug 06 5.625 1589 Aegon Nv AGN INR A1 20.0 110.42 15 Aug 06 8.000 1010 Abbott Labs ABT CNC Aa3 20.0 104.54 01 Jul 06 5.625 711 Caterpillar Inc CAT BAC A2 20.0 105.98 01 May 06 5.950 2412 Coca Cola Enter CCE CNC A2 20.0 102.04 15 Aug 06 5.375 8813 Countrywide Home CCR FIN A3 20.0 101.25 01 Aug 06 5.500 14914 Colgate-Palm Co CL CNC Aa3 20.0 101.43 29 Apr 05 3.980 415 Hershey Foods Co HSY CNC A1 20.0 105.61 01 Oct 05 6.700 216 IBM Corp IBM COT A1 20.0 99.66 01 Oct 06 4.875 2617 Johnson Controls JCI COT A3 20.0 100.30 15 Nov 06 5.000 2418 JP Morgan Chase JPM BNK Aa3 20.0 108.62 01 Jun 05 7.000 4219 Bank One NA ILL ONE BNK Aa3 20.0 101.50 26 Mar 07 5.500 1920 Oracle Corp ORCL COT A3 20.0 105.33 15 Feb 07 6.910 5821 Pub Svc EL & Gas PEG UTL A3 20.0 104.94 01 Mar 06 6.750 3922 Procter & Gamble PG CNC Aa3 20.0 101.76 30 Apr 05 4.000 423 PNC Bank NA PNC BNK A3 20.0 102.26 01 Aug 06 5.750 24EXHIBIT 6.6 Composition of <strong>Bond</strong> Portfolio as of 24 April 2002


120Ticker HCN HLT AAPL DAL AA AAB ANL AC AGN ABT CAT CCE CCR CL HSY IBM JCI JPM ONE ORCL PEG PG PNCHCN 1.000 0.242 0.242 0.242 0.220 0.340 0.340 0.340 0.374 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.242 0.340 0.340 0.242 0.275 0.220 0.374HLT 0.242 1.000 0.198 0.198 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.242 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.198 0.220 0.220 0.198 0.187 0.180 0.242AAPL 0.242 0.198 1.000 0.198 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.242 0.180 0.180 0.198 0.216 0.220 0.220 0.216 0.187 0.180 0.242DAL 0.242 0.198 0.198 1.000 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.242 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.198 0.220 0.220 0.198 0.187 0.180 0.242AA 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 1.000 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.198 0.180 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.170 0.180 0.220AAB 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 1.000 0.374 0.340 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 0.374 0.220 0.250 0.220 0.374ABBEY 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 1.000 0.340 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 0.374 0.220 0.250 0.220 0.374AC 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.340 1.000 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.340 0.220 0.250 0.220 0.340AGN 0.374 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.340 0.340 1.000 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.340 0.220 0.250 0.220 0.340ABT 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 1.000 0.180 0.198 0.220 0.198 0.198 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.170 0.198 0.220CAT 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.198 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.180 1.000 0.180 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.170 0.180 0.220CCE 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.198 0.180 1.000 0.220 0.198 0.198 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.170 0.198 0.220CCR 0.374 0.242 0.242 0.242 0.220 0.340 0.340 0.374 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 1.000 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.242 0.340 0.340 0.242 0.275 0.220 0.374CL 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.198 0.180 0.198 0.220 1.000 0.198 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.170 0.198 0.220HSY 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.198 0.180 0.198 0.220 0.198 1.000 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.170 0.198 0.220IBM 0.220 0.180 0.198 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.180 0.180 1.000 0.198 0.220 0.220 0.198 0.170 0.180 0.220JCI 0.242 0.198 0.216 0.198 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.242 0.180 0.180 0.198 1.000 0.220 0.220 0.216 0.187 0.180 0.242JPM 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 0.374 0.340 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 1.000 0.374 0.220 0.250 0.220 0.374ONE 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 0.374 0.340 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 1.000 0.220 0.250 0.220 0.374ORCL 0.242 0.198 0.216 0.198 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.242 0.180 0.180 0.198 0.216 0.220 0.220 1.000 0.187 0.180 0.242PEG 0.275 0.187 0.187 0.187 0.170 0.250 0.250 0.250 0.250 0.170 0.170 0.170 0.275 0.170 0.170 0.170 0.187 0.250 0.250 0.187 1.000 0.170 0.275PG 0.220 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.198 0.180 0.198 0.220 0.198 0.198 0.180 0.180 0.220 0.220 0.180 0.170 1.000 0.220PNC 0.374 0.242 0.242 0.242 0.220 0.374 0.374 0.340 0.340 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.374 0.220 0.220 0.220 0.242 0.374 0.374 0.242 0.275 0.220 1.000EXHIBIT 6.7 Indicative Asset Return Correlation Matrix for Example Portfolio


Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> 121EXHIBIT 6.8 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Under Default Mode Us<strong>in</strong>g Constant AssetReturn Correlation of 30 percentDescription EL P (mn $) UL P (mn $) %EL P (bp) %UL P (bp)Us<strong>in</strong>g historical PD and / ik 0.660 3.268 13.8 68.6Us<strong>in</strong>g historical PD and ik 0.660 3.334 13.8 69.9Us<strong>in</strong>g KMV’s EDF and / ik 1.175 4.725 24.7 99.1Us<strong>in</strong>g KMV’s EDF and 1.175 4.869 24.7 102.2 ikEXHIBIT 6.9 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Under Default Mode Us<strong>in</strong>g Indicative AssetReturn Correlation MatrixDescription EL P (mn $) UL P (mn $) %EL P (bp) %UL P (bp)Us<strong>in</strong>g historical PD and / ik 0.660 3.136 13.8 65.8Us<strong>in</strong>g historical PD and ik 0.660 3.177 13.8 66.7Us<strong>in</strong>g KMV’s EDF and / ik 1.175 4.489 24.7 94.2Us<strong>in</strong>g KMV’s EDF and 1.175 4.593 24.7 96.4 ikEXHIBIT 6.10Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Under Migration ModeDescription EL P (mn $) UL P (mn $) %EL P (bp) %UL P (bp)Us<strong>in</strong>g constant asset 1.622 4.603 34.0 96.6return correlationof 30 percentUs<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dicative asset 1.622 4.233 34.0 88.8return correlation matrixQUESTIONS1. What are the similarities and differences between aggregation of creditrisk and market risk at the portfolio level?2. Expla<strong>in</strong> the differences between asset return correlation, default correlation,and loss correlation.3. What is model risk? In connection with the quantification of credit risk,is the model risk high or low? Justify your answer.4. It was assumed that recovery rates between two obligors are <strong>in</strong>dependentwhen the expression for loss correlation was derived. If recoveryrates on bonds issued by different obligors are assumed to be positivelycorrelated, will loss correlation be higher or lower? Justify youranswer.5. For the two-bond portfolio example given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.1, compute theexpected and unexpected losses of the portfolio under the default mode


122 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSus<strong>in</strong>g (a) default correlation to aggregate portfolio credit risk, and (b)loss correlation to aggregate portfolio credit risk. Use historical defaultprobabilities <strong>in</strong> the calculations and assume that the asset return correlationbetween obligors is 20 percent.6. How is the leverage ratio of a firm def<strong>in</strong>ed? Discuss why equity returncorrelation is not a good approximation for asset return correlation ifthe firm has a high leverage ratio.7. Discuss the motivation for the use of factor models to derive assetreturn correlation between obligors.8. When comput<strong>in</strong>g the z-thresholds to determ<strong>in</strong>e rat<strong>in</strong>g transitions, itwas assumed that asset returns are standardized normal random variables.Will the z-threshold values differ if the true mean and variance ofthe asset returns are used <strong>in</strong> the calculations? Justify your answer.9. For the two-bond portfolio example given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.1, compute theloss correlation, expected loss, and unexpected loss of the portfoliounder the migration mode. Assume that the asset return correlationbetween the bond obligors is 20 percent.


CHAPTER 7Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss DistributionThe previous chapter dealt with portfolio credit risk quantification us<strong>in</strong>gan analytical approach. Portfolio credit risk was quantified us<strong>in</strong>g the firsttwo moments of the loss distribution, namely expected loss and unexpectedloss (or equivalently the standard deviation of loss). Although these twomeasures are useful, they do not fully model the <strong>in</strong>herent risks <strong>in</strong> a creditportfolio. This is because the distribution of credit losses is highly skewedand has a long, fat tail. As a result, it is difficult to make an estimate of thecredit loss <strong>in</strong> the tail part of the loss distribution for a given confidence levelus<strong>in</strong>g only standard deviation <strong>in</strong>formation. To compute credit loss at higherconfidence levels, one has to resort to simulat<strong>in</strong>g the loss distribution us<strong>in</strong>gMonte Carlo techniques. The advantage of perform<strong>in</strong>g a simulation is thatdifferent tail risk measures can be computed from the simulated loss distribution.When manag<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond portfolio, comput<strong>in</strong>g tail riskmeasures are extremely important if one wishes to avoid concentration riskaris<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>in</strong>sufficient credit diversification.In this chapter, I provide a brief <strong>in</strong>troduction to Monte Carlo methodsand describe the computational process <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> perform<strong>in</strong>g a MonteCarlo simulation to generate the distribution of credit losses. I then <strong>in</strong>troducethe tail risk measures of <strong>in</strong>terest when manag<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bondportfolio and <strong>in</strong>dicate how these risk measures can be computed. Theexample portfolio compris<strong>in</strong>g 23 bonds presented <strong>in</strong> the previous chapter isused to illustrate the concepts presented <strong>in</strong> this chapter.MONTE CARLO METHODSNumerical methods known as Monte Carlo methods can be looselydescribed as statistical simulation methods that make use of sequences ofrandom numbers to perform the simulation. The first documented accountof Monte Carlo simulation dates to the 18th century, when a simulationtechnique was used to estimate the value . However, it is only s<strong>in</strong>ce thedigital computer era that this technique has ga<strong>in</strong>ed scientific acceptance for123


124 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSsolv<strong>in</strong>g complex numerical problems <strong>in</strong> various discipl<strong>in</strong>es. The name“Monte Carlo” was co<strong>in</strong>ed by Nicholis Metropolis while work<strong>in</strong>g on theManhattan Project dur<strong>in</strong>g World War II, because of the similarity of statisticalsimulation to games of chance symbolized by the capital of Monaco.John von Neumann laid much of the early foundations of Monte Carlo simulation,which requires the use of pseudo-random number generators and<strong>in</strong>verse cumulative distribution functions. The application of Monte Carlosimulation techniques to f<strong>in</strong>ance was pioneered by Phelim Boyle <strong>in</strong> 1977 <strong>in</strong>connection with the pric<strong>in</strong>g of options. 1It is tempt<strong>in</strong>g to th<strong>in</strong>k of Monte Carlo methods as a technique for simulat<strong>in</strong>grandom processes that are described by a stochastic differentialequation. This belief stems from the option pric<strong>in</strong>g applications of MonteCarlo methods <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ance, where the underly<strong>in</strong>g variable of <strong>in</strong>terest is theevolution of stock prices, which is described by a stochastic differentialequation. However, this description is too restrictive because many MonteCarlo applications have no apparent stochastic content, such as the evaluationof a def<strong>in</strong>ite <strong>in</strong>tegral or the <strong>in</strong>version of a system of l<strong>in</strong>ear equations.In many applications of Monte Carlo methods, the only requirement is thatthe physical or mathematical quantity of <strong>in</strong>terest can be described by aprobability distribution function.Monte Carlo methods have become a valuable computational tool <strong>in</strong>modern f<strong>in</strong>ance for pric<strong>in</strong>g complex derivative securities and for perform<strong>in</strong>gvalue at risk calculations. An important advantage of Monte Carlo methodsis that they are flexible and easy to implement. Furthermore, the <strong>in</strong>creasedavailability of powerful computers has enhanced the efficiency of thesemethods. Nonetheless, the method can still be slow and standard errors ofestimates can be large when applied to high-dimensional problems or if theregion of <strong>in</strong>terest is not around the mean of the distribution. In such cases, alarge number of simulation runs is required to estimate the variable of <strong>in</strong>terestwith reasonable accuracy. The standard errors on the estimated parameterscan be reduced us<strong>in</strong>g conventional variance reduction procedures suchas the control variate technique or the antithetic sampl<strong>in</strong>g approach.More recent techniques to speed up the convergence of Monte Carlomethods for high-dimensional problems use determ<strong>in</strong>istic sequences ratherthan random sequences. These sequences are known as quasi-randomsequences <strong>in</strong> contrast to pseudo-random sequences commonly used <strong>in</strong> standardMonte Carlo methods. The advantage of us<strong>in</strong>g quasi-randomsequences is that they generate sequences of n-tuples that fill n-dimensionalspace more uniformly than uncorrelated po<strong>in</strong>ts generated by pseudorandomsequences. However, the computational advantage of quasi-randomsequences dim<strong>in</strong>ishes as the number of variables <strong>in</strong>creases beyond 30.An important advantage of Monte Carlo methods is that the computationalcomplexity <strong>in</strong>creases l<strong>in</strong>early with the number of variables. In contrast,


Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss Distribution 125the computational complexity <strong>in</strong>creases exponentially <strong>in</strong> the number ofvariables for discrete probability tree approaches for solv<strong>in</strong>g similar k<strong>in</strong>dsof problems. This po<strong>in</strong>t is best illustrated by consider<strong>in</strong>g the problem ofcredit loss simulation. One approach to comput<strong>in</strong>g the loss distribution ofa two-bond portfolio is to enumerate all possible comb<strong>in</strong>ations of creditstates this portfolio can be <strong>in</strong> after 1 year. Because there are 18 possiblecredit states that each bond can be <strong>in</strong>, the two-bond portfolio could takeone of 324 (18 times 18) credit states. Valu<strong>in</strong>g the credit loss associatedwith each one of the 324 states allows one to derive the credit loss distributionof the two-bond portfolio. If the number of bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio<strong>in</strong>creases to 10, the total number of possible credit states is equal to 18 tothe power 10, which is equal to 3.57 10 12 credit states. Clearly, even withsuch a small portfolio, it is practically impossible to enumerate all the statesand compute the credit loss distribution.If one uses Monte Carlo simulation, on the other hand, the problem complexityrema<strong>in</strong>s the same irrespective of whether the portfolio comprises 2, 10,or more bonds. In each of these cases, one can run several scenarios, each ofwhich corresponds to a simulation run, and under each scenario compute thecredit loss associated with the portfolio. Perform<strong>in</strong>g many simulation runsmakes it possible to compute the credit loss distribution of the bond portfolio.As the number of bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio <strong>in</strong>creases, the computational effort<strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>creases l<strong>in</strong>early <strong>in</strong> the number of bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio.The basic build<strong>in</strong>g blocks for perform<strong>in</strong>g Monte Carlo simulationrequire a scheme to generate uniformly distributed random numbers and asuitable transformation algorithm if the probability distribution of the variablesimulated is different from a uniform distribution. Most applications<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ance require the generation of a normally distributed random variable.To simulate such a random variable, the standard transformation techniquesused are either the Box–Muller method or the <strong>in</strong>verse cumulativenormal method. 2 If the simulated random variables are greater than one, weneed methods to generate correlated random numbers that model therelationship between the variables.CREDIT LOSS SIMULATIONIn Chapter 6, I <strong>in</strong>troduced the notion of latent variables and discussed howthey can be used as a signal<strong>in</strong>g variable for credit events. In particular, Iconsidered the asset return of a firm as a latent variable candidate and <strong>in</strong>dicatedhow asset return thresholds for rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed.Comput<strong>in</strong>g portfolio credit risk requires model<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>t rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations,which <strong>in</strong> turn requires model<strong>in</strong>g the co-movement of asset returns of differentobligors. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that the marg<strong>in</strong>al distribution of asset returns


126 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSis assumed to be normal <strong>in</strong> Merton’s framework, I made the assumptionthat the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is multivariate normal. The jo<strong>in</strong>tevolution of the asset returns of the obligors under the multivariate normaldistribution signal how the value of the portfolio evolves, or equivalently,what the credit loss on the portfolio will be. The distribution of obligorasset returns under the multivariate normal distribution can be generatedus<strong>in</strong>g Monte Carlo simulation. This allows the subsequent computation ofthe loss distribution of the bond portfolio result<strong>in</strong>g from credit events.The forego<strong>in</strong>g description provides the basic <strong>in</strong>tuition beh<strong>in</strong>d the use ofMonte Carlo simulation for comput<strong>in</strong>g the credit loss distribution. In thecontext of its <strong>in</strong>tended use here, the Monte Carlo simulation technique canbe described as a computational scheme that utilizes sequences of randomnumbers generated from a given probability distribution function to derivethe distribution of portfolio credit loss. The distribution of portfolio creditloss can be computed both under the default mode and under the migrationmode. To compute the credit loss under the default mode, one only needsto consider the loss result<strong>in</strong>g from obligor default. Under the migrationmode, one has to compute the credit loss associated with rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations<strong>in</strong> addition to the credit loss result<strong>in</strong>g from obligor default.To generate the credit loss for one run of the Monte Carlo simulation,three computational steps are followed:1. Simulate the correlated random numbers that model the jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionof asset returns of the obligors <strong>in</strong> the portfolio.2. Infer the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of each obligor based on simulated assetreturns.3. Compute the potential loss <strong>in</strong> value based on the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g,and <strong>in</strong> those cases where the asset return value signals an obligordefault, compute a random loss on default value by sampl<strong>in</strong>g from abeta distribution function.Repeat<strong>in</strong>g this simulation run many times and comput<strong>in</strong>g the credit lossunder each simulation run makes it possible to generate the distribution ofportfolio credit loss under the migration mode. If one is only <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong>the credit loss distribution under the default mode, one can compute this bysett<strong>in</strong>g the credit loss associated with rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations to zero <strong>in</strong> the simulationrun. In the follow<strong>in</strong>g sections, I briefly describe the computationalsteps required to generate the credit loss distribution.Generat<strong>in</strong>g Correlated Asset ReturnsI briefly described the steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> simulat<strong>in</strong>g the credit loss distributionfor a bond portfolio. As the first step, I mentioned that correlated random


Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss Distribution 127numbers that model the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns have to be simulated.An immediate question is whether the obligor-specific means andstandard deviations of asset returns have to be taken <strong>in</strong>to account <strong>in</strong> thesimulations. The simple answer to this questions is no. This is because thesimulated asset returns will be compared aga<strong>in</strong>st the rat<strong>in</strong>g migrationthresholds, which were computed under the assumption that asset returnsare standardized normal random variables. As a result, the obligor-specificmean and standard deviation of asset returns are not required for simulat<strong>in</strong>gthe loss distribution. Hence, I assume that obligor asset returns are standardnormal random variables (hav<strong>in</strong>g mean zero and standard deviationequal to one). Under this assumption, the Monte Carlo simulation methodrequires generat<strong>in</strong>g a sequence of random vectors that are sampled from astandardized multivariate normal distribution.Many standard numerical packages provide rout<strong>in</strong>es to generatesequences of random vectors sampled from a multivariate normal distribution.Although the details of the implementation are beyond the scope of thisbook, I briefly outl<strong>in</strong>e the numerical procedure commonly used to generatesequences of multivariate normal random vectors. Assume that the multivariatenormal random vector has a mean vector a and covariance matrix C.Covariance matrices have the property that they are symmetric and positivedef<strong>in</strong>ite (mean<strong>in</strong>g all their eigenvalues are greater than zero). 3 Given such amatrix, it is possible to f<strong>in</strong>d a unique lower triangular matrix L such thatLL T C(7.1)The matrix L is referred to as the Cholesky factor correspond<strong>in</strong>g to the positive-def<strong>in</strong>itematrix C. Once the Cholesky factor is determ<strong>in</strong>ed, generat<strong>in</strong>ga sequence of random vectors with the desired multivariate distributiononly requires generat<strong>in</strong>g a sequence of <strong>in</strong>dependent standard normal randomvariables. If x denotes the vector of <strong>in</strong>dependent standard normal randomvariables, the vector r with the desired multivariate normal distributioncan be constructed as follows:r a Lx(7.2)It is easy to verify from this equation that the sequence of random vectorsr that is generated will have the property that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution ismult<strong>in</strong>ormal with mean vector a and covariance matrix C.It is useful to note here that by sett<strong>in</strong>g the mean vector a to zero andthe covariance matrix equal to the correlation matrix, one can generate asequence of random vectors whose jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution is standardized multivariatenormal. Because the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of obligor asset returns wasassumed to be standardized multivariate normal, this sequence of randomvectors is the one of <strong>in</strong>terest.


128 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSInferr<strong>in</strong>g Implied <strong>Credit</strong> Rat<strong>in</strong>gThe next step <strong>in</strong> the credit loss simulation process is to <strong>in</strong>fer the credit rat<strong>in</strong>gof the various obligors <strong>in</strong> the portfolio as implied by the simulated assetreturn vector. In order to do this, one needs to generalize Merton’s modelto <strong>in</strong>clude thresholds for credit rat<strong>in</strong>g changes <strong>in</strong> addition to the defaultthreshold. The implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g can then be derived on the basis of theasset return value relative to these thresholds. Aga<strong>in</strong>, <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 I derivedthese z-thresholds for different credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs under the assumption that theasset returns are normally distributed. These z-threshold values are given <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 6.3 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6.For purposes of illustration, consider the two-bond portfolio given <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 6.1 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. Assume that for one draw from a bivariate normaldistribution, the random asset returns are respectively 2.5 for bond 1and 3.5 for bond 2. Given the <strong>in</strong>itial issuer rat<strong>in</strong>g of A3 for bond 1, onecan <strong>in</strong>fer from the z-threshold values for A3-rated issuers <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.3 <strong>in</strong>Chapter 6 that an asset return value of 2.5 implies a credit rat<strong>in</strong>g change ofthe issuer to an A1 rat<strong>in</strong>g. Similarly, one can <strong>in</strong>fer from Exhibit 6.3 <strong>in</strong> Chapter6 that an asset return value of 3.5 for an A2-rated issuer implies thatthe issuer defaults on the outstand<strong>in</strong>g debt. Proceed<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this manner, onecan derive the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the debt issuers <strong>in</strong> the two-bond portfoliofor every simulation run on the basis of the z-threshold values <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 6.3 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6.For a general n-bond portfolio, the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the debtissuers for each simulation run can be similarly determ<strong>in</strong>ed. It is importantto note that the number of obligors <strong>in</strong> an n-bond portfolio will be less thanor equal to n. In the case where there are fewer than n obligors, credit rat<strong>in</strong>gchanges should be identical for all bonds issued by the same obligor <strong>in</strong>any simulation run. This has the implication that the dimension of the simulatedasset return vector should be equal to the number of obligors or debtissuers <strong>in</strong> the bond portfolio.Comput<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> LossOnce the implied rat<strong>in</strong>g changes for the obligors are determ<strong>in</strong>ed for the simulatedasset return vector, the correspond<strong>in</strong>g credit loss associated withsuch implied rat<strong>in</strong>g changes could be determ<strong>in</strong>ed. It is important to notethat the price change result<strong>in</strong>g from a rat<strong>in</strong>g change is generically referredto as a loss even though a credit improvement of the obligor results <strong>in</strong> aprice appreciation for the bond. The price change of a bond as a result of arat<strong>in</strong>g change for the bond issuer is a function of the change <strong>in</strong> the yieldspreads and the maturity of the bond. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that our <strong>in</strong>terest is toestimate the credit loss due to a change <strong>in</strong> the bond’s mark-to-market valueas a result of the rat<strong>in</strong>g change, we want to know at what time horizon the


Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss Distribution 129bond’s price has to be marked to market. In Chapter 5, I argued for the casewhere the worst-case loss scenario is computed, which corresponds to a rat<strong>in</strong>gchange of the obligor dur<strong>in</strong>g the next trad<strong>in</strong>g day. In this case, the currenttrad<strong>in</strong>g price of the bond together with its risk parameters durationand convexity serve to characterize the credit loss. The credit loss result<strong>in</strong>gfrom a rat<strong>in</strong>g change from the ith grade to the kth grade is a function of thechange <strong>in</strong> the bond yield and is given by equation (5.32) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 5.To illustrate the credit loss computation, aga<strong>in</strong> focus on the two-bondportfolio example. In this example, the asset return value signaled anupgrade to an A1 rat<strong>in</strong>g from the current rat<strong>in</strong>g of A3 for bond 1. Thechange <strong>in</strong> the yield spread associated with this rat<strong>in</strong>g change is 30 basispo<strong>in</strong>ts, us<strong>in</strong>g the yield spread <strong>in</strong>formation given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 5.8 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 5.Substitut<strong>in</strong>g the various parameter values <strong>in</strong>to equation (5.32) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 5gives the credit loss for a $1 million notional amount held of bond 1 as<strong>Credit</strong> loss 1,000,000 [1.0533 4.021 (0.003) 0.5 1.0533 19.75 (0.003) 2 ]$12,799.6Note that the negative sign associated with the credit loss <strong>in</strong>dicates that thisrat<strong>in</strong>g change results <strong>in</strong> a profit rather than a loss.For bond 2, the simulated asset return value of 3.5 implies default ofthe obligor. In this case, one must f<strong>in</strong>d a random loss on default, which is afunction of the assumed recovery rate distribution. In Chapter 5, the recoveryrate process was assumed to have a beta distribution whose mean andstandard deviation are given by equations (5.15) and (5.16), respectively.Given the values for and , the parameters and that def<strong>in</strong>e the betadistribution with the desired mean and standard deviation can be computedas follows: 2 (1 ) 2(7.3) (7.4)For the bond <strong>in</strong> question, the mean recovery rate is 47 percent and thestandard deviation of the recovery rate is 25 percent. Correspond<strong>in</strong>g tothese recovery rate values, the parameters of the beta distribution functionare 1.403 and 1.582.The random recovery rate for bond 2 for the simulation run is determ<strong>in</strong>edby draw<strong>in</strong>g a random number from a beta distribution with the and parameter values as just given. Assume that the simulated recovery valueis 40 percent for bond 2. The implied loss on default for the bond can nowbe computed us<strong>in</strong>g equation (5.21) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 5, which is equal to 0.6533.


130 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSThe credit loss aris<strong>in</strong>g from bond 2 for this simulation run is equal to thenom<strong>in</strong>al exposure times the loss on default, which is equal to $653,300.For the two-bond portfolio, the total credit loss for this simulation runis the sum of the two losses. If this simulation run corresponds to the ith run,the portfolio credit loss under the ith simulation run, denoted , is given by/ i $12,799.6 $653,300 $640,500.4It is important to emphasize that for a general n-bond portfolio, all bondsof a particular issuer should have the same recovery value for any one simulationrun if they have the same seniority. This <strong>in</strong>formation must be taken<strong>in</strong>to account when simulat<strong>in</strong>g the credit loss distribution of a generaln-bond portfolio.Remarks When simulat<strong>in</strong>g a random recovery amount from a beta distribution,it can happen that this recovery amount is close to the nom<strong>in</strong>alvalue of the bond. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that recovery values tend to be lower thanthe nom<strong>in</strong>al value (typically less than 90 percent of the nom<strong>in</strong>al value), onemay wish to put an upper bound for the recovery amount. In perform<strong>in</strong>gthe loss simulation for an example bond portfolio presented later <strong>in</strong> thischapter, a maximum recovery rate of 90 percent of the nom<strong>in</strong>al value of thebond is imposed. In general, assum<strong>in</strong>g recovery rates to be uniformly distributedis a better approach to restrict<strong>in</strong>g recovery rates to lie with<strong>in</strong> a specificrange. The parameters of the uniform distribution hav<strong>in</strong>g a specifiedmean and standard deviation can be computed as <strong>in</strong>dicated <strong>in</strong> Chapter 2./ iComput<strong>in</strong>g Expected Loss and Unexpected LossThe forego<strong>in</strong>g procedure outl<strong>in</strong>ed how the portfolio credit loss can be computedfor one simulation run. By repeat<strong>in</strong>g the simulation run N timeswhere N is sufficiently large, the distribution of the credit losses can be generated.Given the simulated loss distribution, one can compute various riskmeasures of <strong>in</strong>terest. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the expected and the unexpected creditloss us<strong>in</strong>g the simulated loss data can be computed as follows:EL P 1 N a NUL P B1N 1 a N/ ii1i1(/ i EL P ) 2(7.5)(7.6)To reduce the standard error of the estimated portfolio expected loss, it iscommon practice to perform antithetic sampl<strong>in</strong>g when perform<strong>in</strong>g the


Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss Distribution 131Monte Carlo simulation. The idea beh<strong>in</strong>d antithetic sampl<strong>in</strong>g is that whenrandom samples are drawn from a symmetric distribution, sampl<strong>in</strong>g errorscan be avoided if the antithetic or symmetric part of the random sample isalso drawn. This ensures that the empirical mean of the random samples isequal to the mean of the distribution function from which the samples aredrawn. Includ<strong>in</strong>g the antithetic part of the samples doubles the total numberof simulation runs. All numerical examples presented <strong>in</strong> this book thatuse simulation are generated us<strong>in</strong>g antithetic sampl<strong>in</strong>g. In general, if thenumber of simulation runs is equal to N <strong>in</strong> the numerical examples, one halfof the simulation runs use antithetic samples.Importance Sampl<strong>in</strong>gThe Monte Carlo simulation technique described so far is based on randomsampl<strong>in</strong>g. In such a sampl<strong>in</strong>g process, the probability of any value be<strong>in</strong>ggenerated is proportional to the probability density at that po<strong>in</strong>t. This propertyhas the effect of generat<strong>in</strong>g asset return values <strong>in</strong> the simulations thattend to cluster around the mean of the normal distribution function. Rat<strong>in</strong>gmigrations and obligor defaults, however, are events that are driven byasset return values that deviate significantly from the mean of the normaldistribution. The implication is that a significant proportion of the simulationruns will not trigger any credit events. If one’s <strong>in</strong>tention is to computethe expected and the unexpected loss of the portfolio from the simulations,random sampl<strong>in</strong>g will be the appropriate method to use. If, on the otherhand, one expects to compute risk measures associated with tail eventsfrom the simulated data, random sampl<strong>in</strong>g will be <strong>in</strong>efficient.If one’s primary <strong>in</strong>tention of perform<strong>in</strong>g Monte Carlo simulations is tocompute tail risk measures (to be discussed <strong>in</strong> the next section), one canimprove the simulation efficiency through importance sampl<strong>in</strong>g. 4 Simulationefficiency <strong>in</strong> the present context refers to the number of simulation runsrequired to compute the risk measure of <strong>in</strong>terest for a specified standarderror of the estimate. Importance sampl<strong>in</strong>g artificially <strong>in</strong>flates the probabilityof choos<strong>in</strong>g random samples from those regions of the distribution thatare of most <strong>in</strong>terest. This means that the sampl<strong>in</strong>g process is biased <strong>in</strong> sucha manner that a large number of credit events are simulated relative to whatwould occur <strong>in</strong> practice. In the Monte Carlo simulation term<strong>in</strong>ology, theadjustment made to the probability of a particular po<strong>in</strong>t be<strong>in</strong>g sampled isreferred to as its importance weight. To estimate the true probability distributionof the simulated losses when perform<strong>in</strong>g importance sampl<strong>in</strong>g, onehas to restore the actual probability of each sample by multiply<strong>in</strong>g it by the<strong>in</strong>verse of its importance weight. The numerical results presented <strong>in</strong> thisbook are based only on the standard Monte Carlo simulation technique. Inpractice, when the number of obligors <strong>in</strong> the portfolio is large (this is


132 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSusually true for a benchmark portfolio), perform<strong>in</strong>g importance sampl<strong>in</strong>gleads to improved computational efficiency.TAIL RISK MEASURESThe discussions so far <strong>in</strong> this book focused on the mean and the standarddeviation of the credit loss distribution as appropriate risk measures for acorporate bond portfolio. In the credit risk measurement framework, thesemeasures were referred to as expected loss and unexpected loss, respectively.If the distribution of credit losses is normally distributed, the standard deviationcan be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as the maximum deviation around the mean thatwill not be exceeded with a 66 percent level of confidence. Because thecredit loss distribution is not normal, a similar <strong>in</strong>terpretation to the standarddeviation of credit loss does not hold. In most cases, comput<strong>in</strong>g the probabilityof <strong>in</strong>curr<strong>in</strong>g a large credit loss on a corporate bond portfolio us<strong>in</strong>gunexpected loss <strong>in</strong>formation is usually not possible.In general, a major preoccupation of most corporate bond portfoliomanagers is to structure the portfolio so as to m<strong>in</strong>imize the probability oflarge losses. To do this, an estimate of the potential downside risk of theportfolio becomes a key requirement. Comput<strong>in</strong>g any downside risk measurerequires an estimate of the probability mass associated with the tail ofthe loss distribution. If the simulated credit loss distribution is available, itis quite easy to derive appropriate tail risk measures of <strong>in</strong>terest. For a corporatebond portfolio, the tail risk measures of <strong>in</strong>terest are credit value atrisk and expected shortfall risk. Both these risk measures are discussed <strong>in</strong>what follows, and the method for comput<strong>in</strong>g these measures us<strong>in</strong>g the simulatedcredit loss data is also <strong>in</strong>dicated.<strong>Credit</strong> Value at <strong>Risk</strong><strong>Credit</strong> value at risk (CrVaR) is a tail risk measure that quantifies theextreme losses aris<strong>in</strong>g from credit events that can occur at a prespecifiedlevel of confidence over a given time horizon. In practical terms, CrVaRprovides an estimate of the maximum credit loss on a portfolio that couldbe exceeded with a probability p. It is assumed here that p is expressed <strong>in</strong>percentage. If the probability p is chosen to be sufficiently small, one canexpect that the credit loss will not exceed the CrVaR amount at a high confidencelevel given by (100 p) percent. Stated differently, CrVaR at a confidencelevel of (100 p) percent refers to the maximum dollar value of lossthat will only be exceeded p percent of the time over the given time horizon.Because losses from credit risk are measured over a 1-year horizon, theCrVaR measure to be computed here also relates to a 1-year time horizon.


Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss Distribution 133To compute CrVaR to quantify the tail risk of the credit loss distribution<strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfolio, one needs to specify the confidence levelat which it should be determ<strong>in</strong>ed. With<strong>in</strong> the framework of economic capitalallocation, CrVaR is usually measured at a confidence level that reflectsthe solvency standard of the <strong>in</strong>stitution <strong>in</strong> question. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the solvencystandard of an AA-rated <strong>in</strong>stitution is typically 99.97 percent, andhence CrVaR is computed at this confidence level. From a portfolio managementperspective, however, the confidence level of <strong>in</strong>terest for a CrVaRestimate would typically be much lower. The motivation for this is thatportfolio managers have to provide monthly performance reports to clientsand return deviations over this period need to be expla<strong>in</strong>ed. In this case,estimat<strong>in</strong>g CrVaR at a confidence level of 91.6 percent would imply that theunderperformance relative to the benchmark exceeds the monthly CrVaRestimate once dur<strong>in</strong>g the year on average if monthly performance report<strong>in</strong>gis used. In this case, the a CrVaR estimate provides useful <strong>in</strong>formation tothe portfolio manager and the client <strong>in</strong> terms of the return surprises onecould expect and also what actually happens.Motivated by the this observation, I choose the confidence level for theCrVaR estimate to be 90 percent. At this level of confidence, the portfoliomanager can expect the credit losses to exceed the monthly CrVaR estimatefor one report<strong>in</strong>g period dur<strong>in</strong>g the year. Once the confidence level forCrVaR is specified, estimat<strong>in</strong>g CrVaR from the simulated loss distributionis quite simple. If, for <strong>in</strong>stance, the number of simulation runs is equal to10,000, then the 90 percent CrVaR is equal to the 1,000th worst-case creditloss. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that the simulated credit losses are sorted <strong>in</strong> an ascend<strong>in</strong>gorder of magnitude, the credit loss correspond<strong>in</strong>g to the 9,000th row <strong>in</strong> thesorted data is the CrVaR at 90 percent confidence level for 10,000 simulationruns.Consider<strong>in</strong>g that standard practice <strong>in</strong> portfolio management is toreport risk measures relative to the current market value of the portfolio, I<strong>in</strong>troduce the term percentage credit value at risk. If M P denotes the currentmark-to-market value of the portfolio, the percentage CrVaR at 90 percentconfidence level is def<strong>in</strong>ed as%CrVaR 90% CrVaR 90%M P(7.7)Expected Shortfall <strong>Risk</strong>Although CrVaR is a useful tail risk measure, it fails to reflect the severityof loss <strong>in</strong> the worst-case scenarios <strong>in</strong> which the loss exceeds CrVaR. In otherwords, CrVaR fails to provide <strong>in</strong>sight as to how far the tail of the loss distributionextends. This <strong>in</strong>formation is critical if the portfolio manager is


134 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 7.1<strong>Credit</strong> Loss Distribution for Two <strong>Portfolios</strong>Frequency of lossPortfolio 2Portfolio 1CrVaR(90%)<strong>Credit</strong> loss<strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> restrict<strong>in</strong>g the severity of the losses <strong>in</strong> the worst-case scenariosunder which losses exceed CrVaR. In order to better motivate this po<strong>in</strong>t,Exhibit 7.1 shows the credit loss distribution for two portfolios that haveidentical CrVaR at the 90 percent level of confidence.Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Exhibit 7.1, it is clear that although both portfolios haveidentical CrVaR at the 90 percent confidence level, the severity of theworst-case losses that exceed the 90 percent confidence level are lower forportfolio 1 than portfolio 2. This example suggests that to <strong>in</strong>vestigatewhether portfolio credit risk is well diversified, it is not sufficient to onlyexam<strong>in</strong>e the tail probability at some confidence level. Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the lossexceedence beyond the desired confidence level at which CrVaR is estimatedis important to gauge the loss severity <strong>in</strong> the tail part of the loss distribution.One such risk measure that provides an estimate of the loss severity <strong>in</strong>the tail part of the loss distribution is the expected shortfall risk (ESR),which is sometimes also referred to as conditional VaR. 5 Similar to CrVaR,expected shortfall risk requires specify<strong>in</strong>g a confidence level and a timehorizon. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that ESR is usually used <strong>in</strong> conjunction with CrVaR,the confidence level should be chosen as 90 percent and the time horizon 1year. A simple <strong>in</strong>terpretation of ESR is that it measures the average loss <strong>in</strong>the worst p percent of scenarios, where (100 p) percent denotes the confidencelevel at which CrVaR is estimated. In mathematical terms, expectedshortfall risk can be def<strong>in</strong>ed as the conditional expectation of that part ofthe credit loss that exceeds the CrVaR limit. The <strong>in</strong>terpretation of ESR asconditional VaR follows from this def<strong>in</strong>ition. If/ denotes the loss variable,ESR can be def<strong>in</strong>ed asESR E[/ ƒ/ CrVaR](7.8)


Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss Distribution 135EXHIBIT 7.2Various <strong>Risk</strong> Measures for Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong>Frequency of lossELULCrVaRESR<strong>Credit</strong> lossGiven the simulated loss distribution of the portfolio, comput<strong>in</strong>g expectedshortfall risk is quite simple. Let / i denote the simulated credit loss for theith simulation run and assume that the losses are sorted <strong>in</strong> ascend<strong>in</strong>g order.If the number of simulation runs is equal to N, the relevant equation to computeESR at the 90 percent confidence level from the simulations isN1ESR 90% (1 0.9)N a/ ii0.9 N1(7.9)The percentage ESR at 90 percent confidence level is def<strong>in</strong>ed as%ESR 90% ESR 90%M P(7.10)Exhibit 7.2 shows the various credit risk measures presented here thatcan be computed from the simulated loss data. In the next section, I computethese risk measures by do<strong>in</strong>g a Monte Carlo simulation to generate theloss distribution for an example corporate bond portfolio.NUMERICAL RESULTSIn this section, I aga<strong>in</strong> consider the bond portfolio compris<strong>in</strong>g 23 bondsshown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.6 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 to compute the various credit risk measuresof <strong>in</strong>terest under both the default mode and the migration mode.Because the expected and the unexpected loss of the portfolio can also becomputed directly from the simulated loss data, it will be useful to comparethese values with those obta<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g an analytical expression. In perform<strong>in</strong>gthe loss simulation for the bond portfolio, the asset return correlationmatrix given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.7 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 was used. The simulations were


136 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 7.3Simulated Loss Distribution Under the Migration Mode18%16%14%Frequency of loss12%10%8%6%4%2%0%-7.2-4.10.34.69.013.417.722.126.430.835.139.543.848.252.656.961.365.670.074.378.7<strong>Credit</strong> loss <strong>in</strong> millionsperformed us<strong>in</strong>g antithetic sampl<strong>in</strong>g and the total number of simulationsruns was 500,000. Exhibit 7.3 shows the simulated loss distribution for this23-bond portfolio under the migration mode.In Exhibit 7.3, the negative credit loss refers to an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the markto-marketvalue of the portfolio result<strong>in</strong>g from rat<strong>in</strong>g upgrades for someobligors <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. The simulated loss distribution around the tailregion for this portfolio is shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 7.4.EXHIBIT 7.4Simulated Loss Distribution Around the Tail Region0.25%0.20%Frequency of loss0.15%0.10%0.05%0.00%10.012.915.818.721.624.527.430.333.236.139.041.944.847.750.653.556.459.362.265.168.070.973.9<strong>Credit</strong> loss <strong>in</strong> millions


Simulat<strong>in</strong>g the Loss Distribution 137Exhibit 7.5 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures Under Default Mode Based onSimulated Loss DistributionAmountRelative toDescription (million $) Portfolio Size (bp)Expected loss 0.662 13.9Unexpected loss 3.139 65.9CrVaR at 90 percent confidence 0.0 0.0ESR at 90 percent confidence 6.624 139.0The various portfolio credit risk measures of <strong>in</strong>terest under the defaultmode and the migration mode are presented <strong>in</strong> Exhibits 7.5 and 7.6, respectively.Under the default mode, the probability of default for the obligors <strong>in</strong>the portfolio was chosen to be equal to the historical PD.It is of <strong>in</strong>terest that the expected and unexpected loss figures computedus<strong>in</strong>g the simulated loss distribution are almost identical to the correspond<strong>in</strong>gfigures computed us<strong>in</strong>g the analytical formula presented <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6.The simulation results confirm that under the default mode, loss correlationbetween obligors should be used to aggregate portfolio credit risk. It is also<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to note that under the default mode the CrVaR at 90 percentconfidence level is zero. This is because the probability of obligor defaultsfor this portfolio is much lower. Under the migration mode, the portfoliohas a CrVaR of $4.905 million at the 90 percent confidence level. This hasthe <strong>in</strong>terpretation that there is a 90 percent chance that the credit losses willnot exceed $4.905 million on the portfolio over a 1-year time period.Expected shortfall as a risk measure provides a much better estimateof the tail risk under both the default mode and the migration mode. For<strong>in</strong>stance, under the default mode, the portfolio manager can expect tolose on average $6.624 million on the portfolio if credit events that have10 percent probability occur. Similarly, under the migration mode, theportfolio manager can expect to lose on average $11.452 million on theExhibit 7.6 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures Under Migration Mode Based onSimulated Loss DistributionAmountRelative toDescription (million $) Portfolio Size (bp)Expected loss 1.626 34.1Unexpected loss 4.238 88.9CrVaR at 90 percent confidence 4.905 102.9ESR at 90 percent confidence 11.452 240.3


138 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSportfolio over a 1-year time period if credit events considered hav<strong>in</strong>g 10percent probability of occurrence happen.QUESTIONS1. Discuss the different techniques available to speed up Monte Carlosimulation.2. What is the motivation for perform<strong>in</strong>g a Monte Carlo simulation of thecredit loss distribution?3. What are the ma<strong>in</strong> computational steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> perform<strong>in</strong>g aMonte Carlo simulation of the loss distribution?4. A beta distribution was used to generate random recovery rates ofdefaulted bonds <strong>in</strong> the simulations. If a uniform distribution with thesame mean and standard deviation is used <strong>in</strong>stead, will the expectedand unexpected losses of the portfolio be different? Justify your answer.5. One of the assumptions made when simulat<strong>in</strong>g the loss distribution isthat recovery rates of different obligors are <strong>in</strong>dependent. If this assumptionis relaxed, what changes are needed <strong>in</strong> the Monte Carlo setup tosimulate the loss distribution?6. If the distribution of credit loss is assumed to be normally distributed,would it be necessary to do a Monte Carlo simulation to compute tailrisk measures? Justify your answer assum<strong>in</strong>g that you have computedthe mean and the standard deviation of this loss distribution us<strong>in</strong>g ananalytical approach.7. Imag<strong>in</strong>e a box to be filled with 50 red balls, 30 green balls, 15 whiteballs, and 5 black balls. The payoff for draw<strong>in</strong>g a red ball is $6, a greenball is $5, a white ball is $3, and a black ball is $1. The expected payoffwhen a ball is drawn at random from the box is $5. Will you bewill<strong>in</strong>g to pay $5 to play the game? Is this a fair game?8. In Question 7, assume that two balls of each color have a zero payoffbut the expected payoffs when different-colored balls are drawn are,respectively, $6 for red, $5 for green, $3 for white, and $1 for black.This will ensure that the expected payoff on a ball drawn at random isstill $5. Will you still pay $5 to play the game? Justify why or why not.9. Compute the mean, the standard deviation, the value at risk at 90 percentconfidence level, and the expected shortfall risk at 90 percent confidencelevel of the loss variable (<strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>vestment m<strong>in</strong>us the payofffrom a s<strong>in</strong>gle random draw) assum<strong>in</strong>g that the payoffs for the balls areas given <strong>in</strong> Question 7. Compute the same statistical parameters forQuestion 8.


CHAPTER 8Relax<strong>in</strong>g the NormalDistribution AssumptionThe credit risk analysis presented so far <strong>in</strong> this book is based on theassumption that asset returns of firms are normally distributed. In contrast,virtually most empirical studies report systematic deviation from normality<strong>in</strong> market data. One of the most pervasive features observed acrossequity, foreign exchange, and <strong>in</strong>terest rate markets is excess kurtosis. Theimplication is that, compared to a normal distribution with the same meanand standard deviation, the true distribution assigns greater probability toextreme market moves. Model<strong>in</strong>g the observed excess kurtosis <strong>in</strong> a f<strong>in</strong>ancialtime series requires relax<strong>in</strong>g the normal distribution assumption. Theimplications of relax<strong>in</strong>g the normal distribution assumption for obligorasset returns on various portfolio credit risk measures are the ma<strong>in</strong> focus ofthis chapter.At the obligor level, relax<strong>in</strong>g the assumption that distribution of assetreturns of firms is normal will not change the expected and unexpected losses.In a portfolio context, however, relax<strong>in</strong>g the assumption that jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionof asset returns is multivariate normal can have a significantimpact on the aggregate portfolio credit risk. In fact, the aggregate portfoliocredit risk is usually very sensitive to the exact nature of the jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionof asset returns. In practice, there is no compell<strong>in</strong>g reason, otherthan possibly for computational simplicity, to assume that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionof asset returns of firms is multivariate normal. The extent to whichthe computational overheads <strong>in</strong>crease will depend on the choice of the alternativedistribution function.In this chapter, I discuss methods for comput<strong>in</strong>g the various portfoliocredit risk measures of <strong>in</strong>terest when the asset returns of firms are assumedto have a Student’s t distribution. The reason for choos<strong>in</strong>g the Student’s tdistribution is that it exhibits the property of leptokurtosis, which is commonlyobserved <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial time series data. A distribution function is saidto be leptokurtic if the excess kurtosis (relative to a normal distribution) ispositive. Distributions that are leptokurtic have a higher peak, a narrower139


140 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSmidrange, and fatter tails than a normal distribution function when properlynormalized. Another reason for the choice of the Student’s t distributionis that the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> computational overhead is m<strong>in</strong>imal relative to anormal distribution function. Numerical results are presented at the end ofthe chapter to provide a comparison of portfolio credit risk measuresobta<strong>in</strong>ed under the two different distribution assumptions for asset returnsthat drive credit events.MOTIVATIONA grow<strong>in</strong>g body of empirical studies conducted on f<strong>in</strong>ancial time series datasuggests that returns on traded f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>struments exhibit volatility cluster<strong>in</strong>gand extreme movements that are not representative of a normally distributedrandom variable. Another commonly observed property of f<strong>in</strong>ancialtime series is that dur<strong>in</strong>g times of large market moves, there is greaterdegree of co-movement of returns across many firms compared to thoseobserved dur<strong>in</strong>g normal market conditions. This property, usually referredto as tail dependence, captures the extent to which the dependence (or correlation)between random variables arises from extreme observations. Stateddifferently, for a given level of correlation between the random variables, amultivariate distribution with tail dependence has a much greater tendencyto generate simultaneous extreme values for the random variables than dothose distributions that do not have this property.A multivariate normal distribution does not exhibit tail dependence.The dependence or correlation structure exhibited between the randomvariables <strong>in</strong> a multivariate normal distribution arises primarily from comovementsof the variables around the center of the distribution. As a consequence,contagion or herd<strong>in</strong>g behavior commonly observed <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancialmarkets is difficult to model with<strong>in</strong> the framework of multivariate normaldistributions. To capture contagion and herd<strong>in</strong>g behavior <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets,distributions that exhibit tail dependence should be used to modelf<strong>in</strong>ancial variables of <strong>in</strong>terest. In the context of credit risk model<strong>in</strong>g, contagioneffects result <strong>in</strong> greater co-movement of asset returns across firms dur<strong>in</strong>gperiods of recession, lead<strong>in</strong>g to higher probability of jo<strong>in</strong>t defaults. Ifone models the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns to be multivariate normal,one will fail to capture the effects of contagion <strong>in</strong> the computed aggregateportfolio credit risk measures. 1Student’s t distributionAmong the class of distribution functions that exhibit tail dependence, thefamily of multivariate normal mixture distributions, which <strong>in</strong>cludes the


Relax<strong>in</strong>g the Normal Distribution Assumption 141Student’s t distribution and the generalized hyperbolic distribution, is an<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g alternative. This is because normal mixture distributions <strong>in</strong>heritthe correlation matrix of the multivariate normal distribution. Hence, correlationmatrices for normal mixture distributions are easy to calibrate. 2Formally, a member of the m-dimensional family of variance mixturesof normal distributions is equal <strong>in</strong> distribution to the product of a scalarrandom variable s and a normal random vector u hav<strong>in</strong>g zero mean andcovariance matrix . The scalar random variable s is assumed to be positivewith f<strong>in</strong>ite second moment and <strong>in</strong>dependent of u. If x denotes a randomvector hav<strong>in</strong>g a multivariate normal mixture distribution, then the def<strong>in</strong>itionleads to the follow<strong>in</strong>g equation:x s u(8.1)Because normal mixture distributions <strong>in</strong>herit the correlation matrix of themultivariate normal distribution, one has the follow<strong>in</strong>g relationship:Corr(x i , x k ) Corr(u i , u k )(8.2)The random vector x has a multivariate t distribution with degrees offreedom if the scalar random variable s is def<strong>in</strong>ed as follows:s B(8.3)In equation (8.3), is a chi-square distributed random variable with degrees of freedom. For 2, the result<strong>in</strong>g Student’s t distribution haszero mean vector and covariance matrix [/( 2)]© . Exhibit 8.1 showsEXHIBIT 8.1Probability Density Functions of Normal and t Distributions0.4Student t0.35Normal0.30.250.20.150.10.050-5 -3 -1 1 3 5


142 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSa normal distribution and a Student’s t distribution (with 8) hav<strong>in</strong>gidentical means and variances.The Student’s t distribution has the property that as <strong>in</strong>creases, the distributionapproaches a normal distribution. In fact, for values of greaterthan 25, it is difficult to dist<strong>in</strong>guish between a normal distribution and a tdistribution. In a multivariate sett<strong>in</strong>g, as decreases, the degree of taildependence between the random variables <strong>in</strong>creases. Although the choice ofan appropriate is an open problem <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ance, is typically <strong>in</strong> the rangebetween 5 and 10. In the numerical examples presented <strong>in</strong> this book, Ichoose 8 degrees of freedom for the t distribution.An important dist<strong>in</strong>ction between the t distribution and the normal distributionis that uncorrelated mult<strong>in</strong>ormal random variables are mutually<strong>in</strong>dependent, whereas the components of multivariate t are <strong>in</strong> generaldependent even if they are uncorrelated. In model<strong>in</strong>g credit risk, this propertymakes it possible to capture co-movements of asset returns betweenfirms <strong>in</strong> extreme market situations even if the asset returns exhibit little orno correlation under normal market conditions.Probability Density FunctionIn the univariate case, the probability density function of the Student’s t distributionwith degrees of freedom has the follow<strong>in</strong>g functional form:f (x) (( 1) / 2)2 ( /2) a 1 x2 b (1)/2(8.4)In equation (8.4),()is the gamma function, which is given by() qx 1 e x dx(8.5)0The probability density function of a bivariate t distribution with degreesof freedom and correlation between the two random variables is given byf (x 1 , x 2 ) 1221 a 1 x2 1 x 2 2 2x 1 x 22 (1 2 )(2)/2b(8.6)PORTFOLIO CREDIT RISKIn this section, I revisit the computation of the expected and the unexpectedloss of the portfolio us<strong>in</strong>g an analytical approach when the jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionof asset returns has a t distribution. As mentioned earlier, expected


Relax<strong>in</strong>g the Normal Distribution Assumption 143and unexpected loss at the obligor level will not change when asset returnsare assumed to be t distributed rather than normally distributed. To see whythis is the case, recall that the approach to quantify<strong>in</strong>g credit risk at theobligor level presented <strong>in</strong> Chapter 5 required estimat<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g migrationand default probabilities for the obligor among other variables. Theapproach followed by rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies to compute these probabilities isbased on historically observed rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations of obligor pools. As such,empirical estimation of these probabilities does not require knowledge ofthe default drivers. In the KMV framework, the actual PD estimates for differentobligors is based on empirical data although the approach has thetheoretical underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gs of the Merton framework. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that theactual functional form for the asset return distribution of the obligor doesnot enter <strong>in</strong>to the rat<strong>in</strong>g migration and default probability estimates, theassumption that asset returns have a t distribution has no impact on theseprobabilities. As a result, the expected and the unexpected loss at the obligorlevel are <strong>in</strong>variant under a different distributional assumption for obligorasset returns.At the portfolio level, assum<strong>in</strong>g that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of assetreturns is multivariate t rather than multivariate normal affects the computedportfolio credit risk measures. This is because the loss correlationbetween obligors changes as a result of a change <strong>in</strong> the jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionassumption. It is useful to note that the asset return correlation betweenobligor pairs is the same as <strong>in</strong> the multivariate normal distribution casebecause the multivariate t distribution <strong>in</strong>herits this correlation matrix structure.The change <strong>in</strong> loss correlation arises primarily from the fact that jo<strong>in</strong>tmigration probabilities and jo<strong>in</strong>t default probabilities change when thejo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is assumed to have a multivariate t distribution.The forego<strong>in</strong>g discussion suggests that the portfolio credit risk measuresdiffer due to a change <strong>in</strong> the loss correlation between obligor pairswhen asset returns have a multivariate t distribution. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that theloss correlation parameter does not enter <strong>in</strong>to the portfolio expected losscalculation, the portfolio expected loss would be <strong>in</strong>variant to a change <strong>in</strong>the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns. Hence, <strong>in</strong> this section I focus only onthe portfolio unexpected loss calculation under the default and migrationmodes.Default ModeRecall that the analytical formula for comput<strong>in</strong>g portfolio unexpected lossis given by equation (6.9) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. Under the multivariate t distributionassumption for asset returns, the loss correlation / ik between the ithand the kth obligor is different from that under the multivariate normal


144 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSdistribution assumption. If one follows the same approach as outl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>Chapter 6 to estimate loss correlation between any two obligors, one needsto compute the default correlation between the obligors to <strong>in</strong>fer loss correlation.Default correlation between obligor pairs can be computed given thejo<strong>in</strong>t probability of default between the obligors us<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.14) <strong>in</strong>Chapter 6.The probability of jo<strong>in</strong>t default of two obligors, when asset returns areassumed to be jo<strong>in</strong>tly bivariate t distributed, is given by1prob( i 1, k 1) 221( ik) 2D i Dkq q° 1 x2 y 2 2 (2)/2ikxy¢ dxdy[1 ( ik) 2 ](8.7)In equation (8.7), ik is the asset return correlation between the two obligorsi and k. The <strong>in</strong>tegral limits D i and D k are the default thresholds forobligors i and k, respectively, under the assumption that the asset returnshave a Student’s t distribution. These values can be computed given theprobability of default for each obligor. For <strong>in</strong>stance, if PD i denotes theprobability of default of the ith obligor, D i is the solution to the follow<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>tegral equation:PD i D(( 1)2) i2 (2)qa 1 x2 b (1)/2dx(8.8)Most standard software rout<strong>in</strong>es provide implementations to compute thedeviate D i associated with the lower tail probability PD i of a Student’s t distributionwith degrees of freedom. On the other hand, many software vendorsdo not provide rout<strong>in</strong>es for comput<strong>in</strong>g bivariate t probabilities. However,it is fairly straightforward to compute this us<strong>in</strong>g the algorithmdeveloped by Dunnett and Sobel. 3 A computer program based on this algorithmfor evaluat<strong>in</strong>g the bivariate t probability given by equation (8.7) is<strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the appendix to this chapter.Once the probability of jo<strong>in</strong>t default under the bivariate t distribution isevaluated, default correlation between the two obligors can be determ<strong>in</strong>edus<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.14) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. Then the loss correlation between theobligors can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.19) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. Based on thetwo-bond portfolio example considered <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.1 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6, the variouscredit risk quantities of <strong>in</strong>terest computed under the assumption thatasset returns have a Student’s t distribution are given as follows. The assetreturn correlation between the obligors is aga<strong>in</strong> assumed to be 30 percent.


Relax<strong>in</strong>g the Normal Distribution Assumption 145Us<strong>in</strong>g Historical PD:Jo<strong>in</strong>t default probability prob( i 1, k 1) 7.538 10 5 .Default correlation Loss correlation / ik 0.08346.ik when recovery rates between issuers are <strong>in</strong>dependentis 0.06943.Expected portfolio loss EL P $1,010.Unexpected portfolio loss UL P us<strong>in</strong>g loss correlation is $26,940.Unexpected portfolio loss UL P us<strong>in</strong>g default correlation is $27,113.Us<strong>in</strong>g KMV’s EDF:Jo<strong>in</strong>t default probability prob( i 1, k 1) 1.1184 10 3 .Default correlation Loss correlation / ik 0.10843.ik when recovery rates between issuers are <strong>in</strong>dependentis 0.09006.Expected portfolio loss EL P $11,803.Unexpected portfolio loss UL P us<strong>in</strong>g loss correlation is $91,467.Unexpected portfolio loss UL P us<strong>in</strong>g default correlation is $92,177.Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the results, we note that default and loss correlations are considerablyhigher under the jo<strong>in</strong>t t-distribution assumption for asset returns. For<strong>in</strong>stance, there is almost a sevenfold <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> loss correlation when the jo<strong>in</strong>tdistribution of asset returns is t distributed rather than normally distributed.As a consequence, the estimate of the unexpected loss under the t distributionis higher than what was obta<strong>in</strong>ed assum<strong>in</strong>g jo<strong>in</strong>t normality for asset returns.Migration ModeThe steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> comput<strong>in</strong>g the unexpected loss under the migrationmode under the multivariate t distribution assumption for asset returns followsclosely the procedure outl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. The only difference is thatthe relevant <strong>in</strong>tegral relations to be used to compute the z-thresholds andthe jo<strong>in</strong>t migration probabilities are different. Specifically, the <strong>in</strong>tegrand forcomput<strong>in</strong>g the z-thresholds are the Student’s t density function and the <strong>in</strong>tegrandfor comput<strong>in</strong>g the jo<strong>in</strong>t migration probabilities is the density functionof a bivariate t distribution.For purpose of illustration, consider an obligor that has a current creditrat<strong>in</strong>g of A1. Let P A1,Aaa denote the probability of transition<strong>in</strong>g to the creditrat<strong>in</strong>g Aaa. Under the assumption that the asset returns of the obligor is tdistributed, the credit event that signals the obligor rat<strong>in</strong>g migration fromA1 to Aaa occurs when the asset returns of the obligor exceeds the thresholdz A1,Aaa . This threshold can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed by solv<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g


146 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS<strong>in</strong>tegral equation:P A1,Aaa q(( 1)2) a 1 x2 (1)/22 (2) b dxz A1,Aaa(8.9)A rat<strong>in</strong>g transition of this obligor from A1 to Aa1 occurs if the asset returnfalls between the thresholds z A1,Aaa and z A1,Aa1 . The threshold z A1,Aa1 can bedeterm<strong>in</strong>ed by solv<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tegral equation:P A1,Aa1 z A1,Aaa(( 1)2)2 (2)z A1,Aa1a 1 x2 b (1)/2dx(8.10)One can extend this sequential rule to determ<strong>in</strong>e the thresholds for migrat<strong>in</strong>gto other rat<strong>in</strong>g grades. Aga<strong>in</strong>, it is useful to note here that these z-thresholdsare a function of the current credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the obligor. Exhibit 8.2 showsthe z-threshold values computed us<strong>in</strong>g the normalized rat<strong>in</strong>g transitionprobabilities when asset returns are t distributed.Hav<strong>in</strong>g determ<strong>in</strong>ed the z-threshold values that are used to determ<strong>in</strong>ewhether rat<strong>in</strong>g transitions have occurred, the next step is to compute thejo<strong>in</strong>t migration probabilities. Once aga<strong>in</strong>, for purpose of illustration, considerthe case where the current credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of obligor 1 is A1 and the creditrat<strong>in</strong>g of obligor 2 is A3. Let denote the asset return correlation betweenthe two obligors. The jo<strong>in</strong>t probability that obligor 1 migrates to a B2 rat<strong>in</strong>gand obligor 2 migrates to an Aaa rat<strong>in</strong>g assum<strong>in</strong>g the jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionof asset returns to be bivariate t is given by1h B2,Aaa 221 2z A1,B1z A1,B2q° 1 x2 y 2 2 xy¢(1 2 )z A3,Aaa(2)/2dxdy(8.11)This <strong>in</strong>tegral can be computed once it is transformed <strong>in</strong>to a form that willallow the use of the computer code given <strong>in</strong> the appendix. To do this, usethe follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tegral relation:u 1 u 2l 1l 2f(x, y)dxdy l 1l 2q qf(x, y)dxdy u 1u 2q qf(x, y)dxdy l 1u 2q qf(x,y)dxdy u 1l 2q qf(x,y)dxdy(8.12)In equation (8.12), the <strong>in</strong>tegral limits l 1 , l 2 , u 1 , and u 2 can be either f<strong>in</strong>ite or<strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ite. Mak<strong>in</strong>g use of such a transformation, one can compute numerically


147Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa DefAaa 1.334 1.889 2.538 2.752 3.342 3.923 5.041 5.041 5.041 5.041 6.442 6.442 6.442 6.442 6.442 6.442 6.442 1000Aa1 2.269 0.965 1.400 2.170 3.150 3.598 3.705 4.429 4.429 4.429 5.811 5.811 5.811 5.811 5.811 5.811 5.811 1000Aa2 3.094 2.039 1.093 1.688 2.343 2.937 3.639 4.152 4.152 4.152 4.152 4.152 4.429 5.462 5.462 5.462 5.462 1000Aa3 4.671 3.112 1.967 1.144 1.862 2.553 3.034 3.279 3.618 4.108 4.108 4.304 5.222 5.222 5.222 5.222 5.222 1000A1 5.462 4.250 3.076 1.685 1.235 1.847 2.418 2.731 2.890 2.988 3.355 3.861 4.028 4.775 4.896 4.896 4.896 1000A2 5.041 4.429 3.490 2.773 1.659 1.242 1.861 2.449 2.794 3.076 3.397 3.579 3.861 3.956 4.250 4.429 4.671 1000A3 5.041 4.152 3.956 3.427 2.449 1.351 1.163 1.649 2.176 2.609 2.903 3.051 3.279 3.956 4.152 4.429 4.501 1000Baa1 4.671 4.501 3.861 3.457 3.190 2.094 1.298 1.169 1.733 2.238 2.557 2.773 3.011 3.805 4.108 4.199 4.304 1000Baa2 4.775 4.067 3.682 3.369 3.160 2.596 1.802 1.227 1.274 1.925 2.245 2.388 2.630 2.896 3.316 3.805 3.891 1000Baa3 5.462 5.462 4.896 4.250 3.639 2.937 2.580 1.853 1.110 1.172 1.643 1.974 2.397 2.716 2.903 3.201 3.412 1000Ba1 4.581 4.581 4.581 4.364 3.579 3.369 2.767 2.436 1.829 1.180 1.154 1.462 1.877 2.063 2.368 2.877 3.160 1000Ba2 1000 1000 1000 5.462 4.775 3.891 3.560 3.076 2.621 1.995 1.199 1.041 1.426 1.570 2.058 2.588 2.877 1000Ba3 1000 5.811 5.811 5.811 4.896 3.891 3.473 3.222 2.973 2.576 1.917 1.393 0.989 1.251 1.665 2.113 2.316 1000B1 5.811 5.811 5.811 5.811 4.671 4.067 3.618 3.473 3.150 2.896 2.656 1.982 1.381 0.960 1.231 1.755 2.009 1000B2 1000 1000 4.896 4.775 4.067 4.067 3.832 3.457 3.291 3.094 2.871 2.250 1.765 1.285 0.710 1.202 1.442 1000B3 1000 1000 4.775 4.775 4.581 4.304 3.991 3.660 3.427 3.160 2.988 2.752 2.298 1.644 1.354 0.841 1.173 1000Caa 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 3.304 2.846 2.520 2.520 2.126 1.813 1.663 1.401 0.558 1000Def 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000 1000EXHIBIT 8.2 z-Thresholds Under the t Distribution for Various Rat<strong>in</strong>g Grades


148 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSthe jo<strong>in</strong>t migration probability h B2,Aaa given by equation (8.11). One can followthis procedure to compute the jo<strong>in</strong>t migration probabilities h ik to anyof 324 discrete states for a two-obligor portfolio.The next step <strong>in</strong> the process is to compute the credit loss g ik associatedwith each state of the discrete jo<strong>in</strong>t probability distribution. Here, g ikdenotes the credit loss due to the rat<strong>in</strong>g migration of obligor 1 from state uto state i and of obligor 2 from state to state k. Because this credit loss isnot dependent on the asset return distribution, one can compute this us<strong>in</strong>gequation (6.42) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6.Once the jo<strong>in</strong>t probabilities of be<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> each of the states and the correspond<strong>in</strong>gcredit losses have been determ<strong>in</strong>ed, it is fairly simple to compute theexpected value E(/ 1/ 2) of the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of credit loss us<strong>in</strong>g equation(6.43) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. Insert<strong>in</strong>g this value <strong>in</strong>to equation (6.5) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6allows one to compute the loss correlation between the two obligors underthe migration mode when the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is bivariatet distributed. Once the loss correlation between the obligors is determ<strong>in</strong>ed,comput<strong>in</strong>g the unexpected loss of the portfolio is straightforward.Aga<strong>in</strong> it is <strong>in</strong>structive to compare the expected and the unexpected lossof the two-bond portfolio when asset returns are assumed to be t distributed.The various credit risk measures computed us<strong>in</strong>g the analytical approachpresented here for the two-bond portfolio example considered <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.1<strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 with 30 percent asset return correlation are as follows:The loss correlation / ik under the migration mode is 0.14905.The expected portfolio loss EL P under the migration mode is $4,740.The unexpected portfolio loss UL P under the migration mode is$32,770.As one might expect, the unexpected loss of the portfolio <strong>in</strong>creases due toan <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the loss correlation between the obligors.To provide further comparisons for the credit risk measures obta<strong>in</strong>edwhen the jo<strong>in</strong>t normality of asset returns is relaxed, Exhibit 8.3 shows therisk measures computed for the 23-bond portfolio considered <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.6<strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 assum<strong>in</strong>g a multivariate t distribution for asset returns. In comput<strong>in</strong>gthe expected and unexpected losses for the portfolio, the <strong>in</strong>dicativeEXHIBIT 8.3 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Us<strong>in</strong>g Indicative Asset ReturnCorrelation MatrixDescription EL P (mn $) UL P (mn $) %EL P (bp) %UL P (bp)Under default mode 0.660 3.783 13.8 79.4Under migration mode 1.622 5.034 34.0 105.6


Relax<strong>in</strong>g the Normal Distribution Assumption 149asset return correlation matrix given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.7 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 has beenused. The results aga<strong>in</strong> show an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the portfolio unexpected loss relativeto the multivariate normal distribution assumption for asset returns.For example, the percentage portfolio unexpected loss under the migrationmode <strong>in</strong>creases roughly by 17 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts when the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution ofasset returns is assumed to be multivariate t rather than multivariate normal.LOSS SIMULATIONUnder the assumption that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is multivariatet, I outl<strong>in</strong>ed a computational procedure for evaluat<strong>in</strong>g portfoliounexpected loss us<strong>in</strong>g an analytical approach. To compute the tail risk measures,it is necessary to perform a simulation to generate the credit loss distributionof the portfolio. The steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> simulat<strong>in</strong>g the loss distributionare almost identical to the ones presented <strong>in</strong> Chapter 7 except for onedifference. Instead of generat<strong>in</strong>g the sequence of correlated asset returnsfrom a multivariate normal distribution, it is now necessary to generate thissequence from a multivariate t distribution. In this section, I briefly discussthe procedure for generat<strong>in</strong>g a sequence of random vectors from a multivariatet distribution. Subsequently, I <strong>in</strong>dicate how the credit loss distributioncan be generated under the multivariate t distribution for asset returns.Earlier <strong>in</strong> this chapter, I made the observation that a random vector withmultivariate t distribution hav<strong>in</strong>g degrees of freedom can be derived froma chi-square random variable with degrees of freedom and a random vectorthat is normally distributed and <strong>in</strong>dependent of the chi-square randomvariable. This suggests that by appropriately comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a sequence of multivariatenormal random vectors and a sequence of chi-square distributedrandom variables with degrees of freedom, a sequence of multivariatet-distributed random vectors with degrees of freedom can be simulated.The procedure for generat<strong>in</strong>g a sequence of random vectors from amultivariate normal distribution was discussed <strong>in</strong> Chapter 7. Hence, I donot purse this further <strong>in</strong> this section. To generate a sequence of chi-squaredistributed random variables, the standard procedure is to use the relationshipbetween a chi-square distribution and a gamma distribution. A randomvariable x is said to have a gamma distribution if its density functionis def<strong>in</strong>ed as follows:1()f(x) e x1 e x/ , x 00, x 0(8.13)In equation (8.13), 0 and 0 are the parameters of the gammadistribution and () is the gamma function given by equation (8.5). The


150 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSchi-square distribution with degrees of freedom is a special case of thegamma distribution with parameter values /2 and 2.Given the forego<strong>in</strong>g relationship between a gamma and a chi-squaredistribution, a sequence of random variables hav<strong>in</strong>g a chi-square distributionwith degrees of freedom can be generated by sampl<strong>in</strong>g from a gammadistribution with parameter values /2 and 2. Most standard softwarepackages provide rout<strong>in</strong>es for generat<strong>in</strong>g random sequences from agamma distribution. Hence, I do not discuss the details concerned with generat<strong>in</strong>gsuch a sequence of random variables.To summarize, the follow<strong>in</strong>g are the steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g ann-dimensional sequence of multivariate t distributed random variables with degrees of freedom:Step 1. Compute the Cholesky factor L of the matrix C, where C is the n nasset return correlation matrix.Step 2. Simulate n <strong>in</strong>dependent standard normal random variatesz i , z 2 ,...,z n and set u Lz.Step 3. Simulate a random variate from a chi-square distribution with degrees of freedom that is <strong>in</strong>dependent of the normal random variatesand set S 1 1.Step 4. Set x s u, which represents the desired n-dimensional t variatewith degrees of freedom and correlation matrix C.Repeat<strong>in</strong>g steps 2 to 4 allows one to generate the sequence of multivariatet-distributed random variables.Comput<strong>in</strong>g the credit loss under each simulation run will require compar<strong>in</strong>gthe asset return values aga<strong>in</strong>st the z-thresholds given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 8.2 totrigger rat<strong>in</strong>g migrations and defaults for the obligors <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. Onthe basis of the implied rat<strong>in</strong>g changes for the obligors us<strong>in</strong>g simulated assetreturns, the credit loss for each simulation run can be calculated. The rest ofthe steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> comput<strong>in</strong>g the credit risk measures of <strong>in</strong>terest from thesimulated loss distribution are identical to the ones outl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Chapter 7.Exhibits 8.4 and 8.5 show the various portfolio credit risk measuresevaluated for the 23-bond portfolio given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.6 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 underEXHIBIT 8.4 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures Under Default Mode Based onSimulated Loss Distribution and Historical PDRelative toDescription Amount (million $) Portfolio Size (bp)Expected loss 0.659 13.8Unexpected loss 3.750 78.7CrVaR at 90 percent confidence 0.0 0.0ESR at 90 percent confidence 6.593 138.3


Relax<strong>in</strong>g the Normal Distribution Assumption 151EXHIBIT 8.5 Portfolio <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures Under Migration Mode Based onSimulated Loss DistributionRelative toDescription Amount (million $) Portfolio Size (bp)Expected loss 1.621 34.0Unexpected loss 5.009 105.1CrVaR at 90 percent confidence 4.602 96.6ESR at 90 percent confidence 12.211 256.2the default mode and the migration mode, respectively. These measureswere computed with eight degrees of freedom for the multivariate t distribution,and the <strong>in</strong>dicative asset return correlation matrix given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit6.7 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 was used to generate correlated asset returns. The simulationswere performed us<strong>in</strong>g antithetic sampl<strong>in</strong>g and the total number ofsimulation runs was 500,000.In compar<strong>in</strong>g the credit risk measures shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 7.5 <strong>in</strong> Chapter7 aga<strong>in</strong>st those <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 8.4, one can make the <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g observation thatthere is a marg<strong>in</strong>al reduction <strong>in</strong> the ESR at the 90 percent confidence levelunder the default mode when the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns isassumed to be t distributed with eight degrees of freedom. Under the migrationmode, however, ESR at the 90 percent confidence level is roughly 16basis po<strong>in</strong>ts higher when the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is assumed tobe t distributed with eight degrees of freedom. The credit VaR at the 90 percentconfidence level, on the other hand, is lower when asset returns have amultivariate t distribution. This observation once aga<strong>in</strong> illustrates thatCrVaR as a tail risk measure needs to be used with some caution because itdoes not reflect the potential losses when losses exceed this amount.APPENDIXThe follow<strong>in</strong>g C program implementation for comput<strong>in</strong>g the bivariate tprobability given by equation (8.7) uses f<strong>in</strong>ite sums of <strong>in</strong>complete betafunctions:Description:Arguments:Function for comput<strong>in</strong>g the bivariate tprobabilitynu is the number of degrees of freedomdh is the upper limit of the first<strong>in</strong>tegraldk is the upper limit of the second<strong>in</strong>tegral


152 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSReturn value:Reference:Remarks:rho is the correlation between two trandom variablesBivariate probability as a doubleThis algorithm is based on the methoddescribed by C. W. Dunnett and M.Sobel (1954), “A Bivariate Generalizationof Student’s t-Distributionwith Tables for Certa<strong>in</strong> SpecialCases,”Biometrika, vol. 41, pp. 153–169The C implementation is based on aFORTRAN code provided by Alan Genzat the follow<strong>in</strong>g Web site:www.sci.wsu.edu/math/faculty/genz/homepagedouble bivariate_t_probability (double nu, double dh,double dk, double rho){<strong>in</strong>t i, k;double pi, ors, hrk, krh, bvt, snu, hs, ks;double gmph, gmpk, xnkh, xnhk, qhrk, hkn, hpk, hkrn;double btnckh, btnchk, btpdkh, btpdhk, idouble, <strong>in</strong>tpart;if ((nu < 1.0) || fabs(rho) > 0.9999)return (–1.0); /* signal an error */pi = acos(-1.0);snu = sqrt(nu);ors = 1.0 – rho*rho;hrk = dh – rho*dk;krh = dk – rho*dh;if ((fabs(hrk) + ors) > 0.0){xnhk = hrk*hrk/(hrk*hrk + ors*(nu + dk*dk));xnkh = krh*krh/(krh*krh + ors*(nu + dh*dh));}else{xnhk = 0.0;xnkh = 0.0;}hs = ((dh-rho*dk) < 0.0)? –1.0:1.0;ks = ((dk-rho*dh) < 0.0)? –1.0:1.0;if (modf(nu/2.0, &<strong>in</strong>tpart)


Relax<strong>in</strong>g the Normal Distribution Assumption 153{bvt = atan2(sqrt(ors), -rho)/(2.0*pi);gmph = dh/sqrt(16.0*(nu + dh*dh));gmpk = dk/sqrt(16.0*(nu + dk*dk));btnckh = 2.0*atan2(sqrt(xnkh), sqrt(1.0 - xnkh))/pi;btpdkh = 2.0*sqrt(xnkh*(1.0 - xnkh))/pi;btnchk = 2.0*atan2(sqrt(xnhk), sqrt(1.0 - xnhk))/pi;btpdhk = 2.0*sqrt(xnhk*(1.0 - xnhk))/pi;k = (<strong>in</strong>t) (nu/2.0);for (i=1; i


154 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSbvt = bvt + gmpk*(1.0 + hs*btnchk);btpdkh = (idouble – 1.0)*btpdkh*(1.0 – xnkh)/(idouble);btnckh = btnckh + btpdkh;gmph = idouble*gmph/((idouble + 1.0)*(1.0 + dh*dh/nu));gmpk = idouble*gmpk/((idouble + 1.0)*(1.0 + dk*dk/nu));}}return(bvt);}QUESTIONS1. What are the drawbacks of model<strong>in</strong>g the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of assetreturns as a multivariate normal?2. Discuss the motivation for us<strong>in</strong>g Student’s t distribution to model thejo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns.3. How will the credit loss distribution of a portfolio be affected as thenumber of degrees of freedom of the multivariate t distribution used tomodel the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is reduced?4. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that the probability of default of an obligor is 50 basispo<strong>in</strong>ts, compute the z-threshold value that will trigger a default whenthe obligor’s asset returns are modeled as (a) normally distributed and(b) Student’s t distributed with eight degrees of freedom.5. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns is bivariate t distributedwith eight degrees of freedom, compute the unexpected loss ofthe two-bond portfolio example given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.1 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6under the default mode us<strong>in</strong>g (a) default correlation to aggregate portfoliocredit risk and (b) loss correlation to aggregate portfolio creditrisk. Use historical default probabilities <strong>in</strong> the calculations and assumethat the asset correlation between obligors is 20 percent.6. Describe the steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> simulat<strong>in</strong>g a sequence of a multivariatet-distributed random vector.


CHAPTER 9<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g andPerformance AttributionPortfolio management is concerned with the process of manag<strong>in</strong>g the riskof a portfolio relative to a benchmark with the purpose of either track<strong>in</strong>gor add<strong>in</strong>g value. In order to manage the risks relative to a benchmark,a framework for risk measurement has to be established. In Chapters 4 to8, I discussed how market risk and credit risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfoliocould be quantified, which <strong>in</strong> turn established the framework for riskmeasurement. For market risk measurement, I <strong>in</strong>troduced the concept oftrack<strong>in</strong>g error to measure the market risk of a portfolio relative to a benchmark.The credit risk measures I <strong>in</strong>troduced, on the other hand, are primarilyabsolute risk measures for the portfolio.When portfolios are managed on behalf of clients, communicat<strong>in</strong>g therisks of the portfolio relative to the benchmark becomes a requirement. Tomeet this requirement, one needs to develop a framework for risk report<strong>in</strong>g.In develop<strong>in</strong>g the risk-report<strong>in</strong>g framework, it is important to keep <strong>in</strong>m<strong>in</strong>d that the risk reports that are generated should be simple and <strong>in</strong>tuitiveso that they improve the effectiveness of risk communication. For <strong>in</strong>stance,the risk report should be able to provide <strong>in</strong>sight on potential return deviationsthat can arise due to mismatches <strong>in</strong> risk exposures between the portfolioand the benchmark. In particular, the risk report should be able toidentify risk sources that can lead to an underperformance aga<strong>in</strong>st thebenchmark. The usefulness of the risk report is further enhanced if, on thebasis of the <strong>in</strong>formation it conta<strong>in</strong>s, one can quantify the magnitude ofpotential underperformance and its associated probability. F<strong>in</strong>ally, it isimportant to ensure that the risk report offers drill-down capability. Drilldowncapability is a jargon that is used to refer to the ability of a risk reportto provide different levels of granularity to meet the report<strong>in</strong>g requirementsof different <strong>in</strong>terest groups.A related and equally important requirement <strong>in</strong> the portfolio managementbus<strong>in</strong>ess is to report the performance of the portfolio and expla<strong>in</strong> thefactors that led to differences <strong>in</strong> return versus the benchmark. This process,155


156 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSwhich <strong>in</strong>volves analyz<strong>in</strong>g the portfolio performance and its relative performanceaga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark <strong>in</strong> terms of the decisions that led to differences<strong>in</strong> returns, is usually referred to as performance attribution.Together, risk report<strong>in</strong>g and performance attribution constitute the focalpo<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> the relationship between the manager and the fiduciary oversee<strong>in</strong>gthe prudent management of the assets.In this chapter, I develop a framework for report<strong>in</strong>g the credit risk andmarket risk of a corporate bond portfolio that is managed aga<strong>in</strong>st a benchmark.To emphasize the po<strong>in</strong>t that the risk estimates presented <strong>in</strong> the riskreport are subject to model risk, I present the credit risk report under bothmultivariate normal distribution and multivariate t-distribution assumptionsfor the asset returns. I also briefly mention the types of risk guidel<strong>in</strong>esa client can enforce when a corporate bond portfolio mandate is awarded.F<strong>in</strong>ally, I discuss performance attribution and develop a simple performanceattribution model for identify<strong>in</strong>g the sources for excess returns aga<strong>in</strong>st thebenchmark for corporate bond portfolios.RELATIVE CREDIT RISK MEASURESStandard <strong>in</strong>dustry practice is to quantify the risk of a portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st abenchmark <strong>in</strong> terms of track<strong>in</strong>g error. Track<strong>in</strong>g error is a statistical measureof risk that <strong>in</strong>dicates the range of possible outcomes surround<strong>in</strong>g meanvalue. Formally, track<strong>in</strong>g error is the annualized standard deviation of thedifference between portfolio return and benchmark return. If it is assumedthat the returns are normally distributed, then there is an equal probabilityof returns be<strong>in</strong>g higher or lower than the average outperformance. There isalso approximately a 1 <strong>in</strong> 3 chance of returns be<strong>in</strong>g greater than one standarddeviation from the mean value. From a downside risk perspective,track<strong>in</strong>g error for normally distributed returns can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as themagnitude of underperformance that will be exceeded only on 1 <strong>in</strong> 6 occasions.Equivalently, track<strong>in</strong>g error can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as the relative value atrisk of a portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st its benchmark at 83 percent confidence level.Such an <strong>in</strong>terpretation is based on the assumption that returns are normallydistributed with a zero mean value.In general, track<strong>in</strong>g error as a risk measure can be used to substantiatepast performance or to predict future performance. Historical track<strong>in</strong>gerrors are based on observed excess returns between the portfolio and thebenchmark. Comput<strong>in</strong>g future or ex ante track<strong>in</strong>g errors, on the otherhand, requires estimat<strong>in</strong>g a risk model. To estimate such a risk model, oneneeds to specify a set of risk factors that captures the exposure to differentsources of risk. 1 Such an approach, although appropriate for quantify<strong>in</strong>gmarket risk relative to the benchmark, will fail to adequately reflect the true


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 157level of credit risk. This is because the risk model is merely a representationof market-driven volatility and correlation observed among the risk factorsand is estimated us<strong>in</strong>g daily or weekly time series data. <strong>Credit</strong> events, on thecontrary, are events that occur <strong>in</strong>frequently and hence will not be capturedwhen daily or weekly time series data are collected over a limited timeframe, a practice that is common for market risk measurement. Hence, present<strong>in</strong>ga risk report for a corporate bond portfolio on the basis of track<strong>in</strong>gerror will fail to capture the true risks aris<strong>in</strong>g from credit events.In order to properly quantify and report credit risk relative to a benchmark,one needs to move away from the track<strong>in</strong>g error framework. Beforedo<strong>in</strong>g this, however, it is useful to reflect upon the philosophy beh<strong>in</strong>d theapproach used to compute ex ante track<strong>in</strong>g error. In broad terms, theapproach identifies common risk factors between the portfolio and the benchmarkand then uses the difference <strong>in</strong> exposures to these risk factors as ameans of comput<strong>in</strong>g ex ante track<strong>in</strong>g error. The difficulty <strong>in</strong> try<strong>in</strong>g to extendthis approach to compute relative credit risk is that the notion of commonrisk factors was not <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> credit risk. Instead, every obligor <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong>sense qualified to be a risk factor. In the absence of common factors, onealternative to quantify<strong>in</strong>g relative risk would be to compute the differencebetween the absolute risk measures for the portfolio and the benchmark.The ma<strong>in</strong> drawback with the quantification of relative risk <strong>in</strong> this manner isthat one cannot estimate the magnitude of potential underperformance andits associated probability. In this section, I develop a method to compute arelative measure of credit risk that meets this requirement.The composition of any portfolio that <strong>in</strong>tends to replicate a benchmarkcan be seen as compris<strong>in</strong>g long and short positions aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmarkweights for the constituent bonds <strong>in</strong> the benchmark portfolio. When thereare no long or short positions versus the constituent bonds <strong>in</strong> the benchmark,there will be no residual risk and hence the relative credit and marketrisk between the portfolio and benchmark will be zero. The relativecredit risk between the portfolio and the benchmark can be seen as the creditrisk of a portfolio that has net long and short positions <strong>in</strong> the respectivebonds that constitute the benchmark. For those bonds held <strong>in</strong> the portfolionot conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the benchmark, one simply extends the composition of thebenchmark by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g these bonds with a zero weight.To derive the relative credit risk measure, assume the benchmark comprisesn bonds. The portfolio that is set up to replicate the risks of the benchmarkwill, <strong>in</strong> general, comprise only a subset of the bonds <strong>in</strong> the benchmark.However, for mathematical exposition one can consider the portfolio toalso comprise n bonds with zero nom<strong>in</strong>al exposures for those bonds thatare not held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. For the portfolio, let the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure tothe ith bond be NE i,P and let M P be the mark to market value of the portfolio.Let the correspond<strong>in</strong>g values for the benchmark be NE i,B and M B ,


158 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSrespectively. The relative credit risk between the portfolio and the benchmarkcan be seen as the credit risk of an active portfolio, whose nom<strong>in</strong>alexposure to the ith bond is given byNE i,A a NE i,P NE i,B M PM Bb(9.1)Note that by construction some of the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposures of the active portfoliowill be positive and others negative. Given the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure NE i,Afor ith bond <strong>in</strong> the active portfolio, it is easy to compute the unexpected lossof the ith bond and hence the unexpected loss of the active portfolio us<strong>in</strong>gequation (6.9) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. The unexpected loss of the active portfolio providesuseful <strong>in</strong>formation concern<strong>in</strong>g the relative credit risk between the portfolioand the benchmark. However, because the distribution of relative creditlosses between two portfolios is not normal, it is difficult to provide aprobabilistic <strong>in</strong>terpretation to the level of underperformance aga<strong>in</strong>st thebenchmark based on this risk measure.I <strong>in</strong>dicated that the relative risk measure would be useful under the conditionthat it captures both the magnitude and the probability of underperformance.In the absence of <strong>in</strong>formation concern<strong>in</strong>g the shape of the creditloss distribution of the portfolio with nom<strong>in</strong>al exposures give by equation(9.1), the approach to measur<strong>in</strong>g relative risk that meets this objectiverequires simulat<strong>in</strong>g the relative credit loss distribution. This makes it possibleto compute relative credit risk measures that reflect both the magnitudeof underperformance and its associated probability.Generat<strong>in</strong>g the loss distribution for a portfolio with nom<strong>in</strong>al exposuresgiven by equation (9.1) is fairly straightforward if one follows the approachoutl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Chapter 7 or Chapter 8. Once the loss distribution is simulated,credit value at risk and expected shortfall risk at 90 percent confidence levelcan be computed as <strong>in</strong>dicated <strong>in</strong> Chapter 7. Consider<strong>in</strong>g that this loss distributionis associated with a portfolio that captures the relative credit riskaris<strong>in</strong>g from tak<strong>in</strong>g long and short positions aga<strong>in</strong>st the bonds constitut<strong>in</strong>gthe benchmark, I refer to these risk measures as relative CrVaR and relativeESR, both estimated at a 90 percent level of confidence.To illustrate the relative credit risk measures def<strong>in</strong>ed here, I present anumerical example. Specifically, the portfolio compris<strong>in</strong>g 23 bonds given <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 6.6 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 is considered to represent the benchmark portfolio.Assume that the actual portfolio held to replicate the benchmark consists of7 bonds and residual cash (Exhibit 9.1). The hold<strong>in</strong>gs of this portfolio aregiven <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.1, and the mark to market value of the portfolio is equalto USD 73.0 million.Under the assumption that the asset returns of obligors are multivariatenormal, the simulated loss distribution of the relative credit risk between


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 159EXHIBIT 9.1 Composition of Portfolio Held as of 24 April 2002S. Issuer Nom<strong>in</strong>al Dirty CouponNo. Issuer Ticker Industry Rat<strong>in</strong>g USD mn Price Maturity (%)1 Health Care Reit HCN INR Ba1 10.0 99.91 15 Aug 07 7.5002 Alcoa Inc AA BAC A1 10.0 105.24 1 Jun 06 5.8753 Abbey Natl Plc ABBEY BNK Aa3 10.0 108.43 17 Nov 05 6.6904 Countrywide Home CCR FIN A3 10.0 101.25 1 Aug 06 5.5005 Colgate-Palm Co CL CNC Aa3 10.0 101.43 29 Apr 05 3.9806 Oracle Corp ORCL COT A3 10.0 105.33 15 Feb 07 6.9107 Pub Svc EL & Gas PEG UTL A3 10.0 104.94 1 Mar 06 6.7508 Cash (1.75% p.a.) 0.35 100.00 30 Apr 02 1.750the portfolio held and the benchmark is shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.2. The simulationswere performed under the migration mode us<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>dicative assetreturn correlation matrix given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.7 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. In Exhibit 9.2,negative losses correspond to a profit, which arises primarily from the shortpositions held <strong>in</strong> many bonds. These short positions are measured relativeto the benchmark weights for these bonds. One can see from Exhibit 9.2that there is scope for both underperformance and outperformance relativeto the benchmark. To highlight the loss distribution <strong>in</strong> the tail regions,Exhibit 9.3 shows the simulated losses with the peak of the distributionclipped.It is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to note from Exhibit 9.3 that the magnitude of potentialunderperformance (right tail region) is greater than the potential outperformancethat can be generated aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark. Although theprobability of small outperformance is large, there is a small probability ofEXHIBIT 9.2Relative <strong>Credit</strong> Loss Distribution Under the Migration Mode25%Frequency of loss20%15%10%5%0%-8.3-5.7-4.6-3.8-3.1-2.3-1.6-0.8-0.10.71.42.22.93.74.45.25.96.77.48.28.99.710.4Relative credit loss (millions)


160 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 9.3Relative <strong>Credit</strong> Loss Distribution Under the Migration Mode1.0%Frequency of loss0.8%0.6%0.4%0.2%0.0%-8.3-5.7-4.6-3.8-3.1-2.3-1.6-0.8-0.10.71.42.22.93.74.45.25.96.77.48.28.99.710.4Relative credit loss (millions)large underperformance aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark. Quantify<strong>in</strong>g relative creditrisk <strong>in</strong> terms of track<strong>in</strong>g error fails to pick up these differences.From the simulated losses, the relative credit risk measures of <strong>in</strong>terestcan be easily computed. These are shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.4. The unexpectedloss of the active portfolio computed us<strong>in</strong>g equation (6.9) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 isalso shown <strong>in</strong> this exhibit. The relative CrVaR measure <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.4 suggeststhat there is a 10 percent chance over a 1-year period that the portfoliowill underperform the benchmark by more than 38 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. Theaverage underperformance <strong>in</strong> the worst-case 10 percent scenarios is roughlyequal to 126 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts.MARGINAL CREDIT RISK CONTRIBUTIONIn the previous section, I showed how the relative credit risk of the portfolioaga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark can be quantified. Although useful, such a riskmeasure does not identify the sources that contribute to the relative creditrisk. Portfolio managers entrusted with the task of manag<strong>in</strong>g the risks relativeto a given benchmark need to have the relative credit risk disaggregatedEXHIBIT 9.4Relative <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures Under the Migration ModeAmount Relative toDescription ($) Portfolio Size (bp)UL of active portfolio 653,000 89.5Relative CrVaR at 90 percent confidence 282,000 38.6Relative ESR at 90 percent confidence 918,000 125.8


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 161so that the ma<strong>in</strong> risk drivers can be identified. This is necessary to make<strong>in</strong>formed decisions on what bonds to buy and sell <strong>in</strong> order to mitigate riskconcentrations. This leads to the topic of marg<strong>in</strong>al credit risk contribution.In broad terms, the marg<strong>in</strong>al contribution to total risk from a bond canbe def<strong>in</strong>ed as the rate of change <strong>in</strong> risk with respect to a small percentagechange <strong>in</strong> the bond hold<strong>in</strong>g. If the risk measure <strong>in</strong> question is the unexpectedloss of the portfolio, the marg<strong>in</strong>al risk measure is referred to as theunexpected loss contribution (ULC). The unexpected loss contribution ofthe ith bond identifies the total amount of risk <strong>in</strong> the portfolio that is attributableto the ith bond. Formally, the ULC of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio isdef<strong>in</strong>ed asULC i UL i 0UL P0UL i(9.2)By perform<strong>in</strong>g the differentiation, one can show that the unexpected losscontribution aris<strong>in</strong>g from the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio is given byULC i nUL i a UL k / ikk1UL P(9.3)An attractive feature of ULC as a marg<strong>in</strong>al risk contribution measure isthat the sum of the risk contributions of the <strong>in</strong>dividual bonds is equal to thetotal unexpected loss of the portfolio. In other words, the follow<strong>in</strong>g relationholds:UL P ani1ULC i(9.4)This additivity property ensures that one can correctly identify the diversificationeffects of <strong>in</strong>dividual bonds held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. If one works directlywith the unexpected loss of the active portfolio, the unexpected loss contributionwill identify the sources that contribute to the relative credit riskbetween the portfolio and the benchmark. I denote the unexpected loss ofthe active portfolio by UL A and the unexpected loss contribution aris<strong>in</strong>gfrom the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the active portfolio by ULC i,A .A risk report that identifies the risk contribution aris<strong>in</strong>g from everybond <strong>in</strong> the benchmark is not very useful. Typically this could be severalthousands for an <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bond benchmark. To makethe risk report mean<strong>in</strong>gful, one has to group the bonds <strong>in</strong>to subsets thathave certa<strong>in</strong> attributes. These attributes should be chosen such that theyhave an <strong>in</strong>tuitive <strong>in</strong>terpretation. The aggregated risk contribution aris<strong>in</strong>gfrom such group<strong>in</strong>gs then provides a more mean<strong>in</strong>gful risk report.


162 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSPotential attributes on which such group<strong>in</strong>gs can be done are the<strong>in</strong>dustrial sector and the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the bond obligor. Comput<strong>in</strong>g themarg<strong>in</strong>al risk contribution based on such group<strong>in</strong>gs to the total relativecredit risk enhances the usefulness of the risk report considerably. For<strong>in</strong>stance, if one wishes to calculate the unexpected loss contribution ofAa1-rated obligors to the unexpected loss of the active portfolio, one needsto sum the unexpected loss contributions of all bonds that have this obligorrat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the active portfolio. Similarly, to compute the unexpected losscontribution of bonds that belong to the utilities sector <strong>in</strong> the active portfolio,one needs to sum the unexpected loss contributions of all bonds thatbelong to this sector. If the unexpected loss contribution of each bond is<strong>in</strong>dexed by the obligor rat<strong>in</strong>g R and the <strong>in</strong>dustrial sector I of the bond,comput<strong>in</strong>g the unexpected loss contribution from Aa1-rated obligors tothe unexpected loss of the active portfolio boils down to evaluat<strong>in</strong>g thefollow<strong>in</strong>g summation:ULC A (AaI) ani1RAa1ULC i,A (R,I)(9.5)In practice, the unexpected loss contributions will be more <strong>in</strong>formative ifthey are reported relative to the portfolio size. This requires divid<strong>in</strong>g theunexpected loss contributions <strong>in</strong> equation (9.5) by the mark to marketvalue of the actual portfolio held. In the next section, I present a samplecredit risk report where the benchmark is taken to be the list of bonds given<strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.6 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 and the actual portfolio held is taken to be theone given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.1.PORTFOLIO CREDIT RISK REPORTActive portfolio management focuses on outperform<strong>in</strong>g the return of aspecified benchmark without tak<strong>in</strong>g undue risks while achiev<strong>in</strong>g this objective.Several <strong>in</strong>dustrywide standards, such as the Global Industry PerformanceStandards or Standards of the Association for Investment Managementand Research, exist on how to measure and report the added valuerelative to a benchmark. On the contrary, standards for measur<strong>in</strong>g andreport<strong>in</strong>g portfolio risk relative to a benchmark are practically nonexistenteven for market risk. Part of the reason for this is that to measure risk, onehas to choose a risk model <strong>in</strong> the first place. The choice of the appropriaterisk factors that govern the risk model <strong>in</strong>fluence how well the risk model isable to capture the <strong>in</strong>herent risks. One could argue that there are broadguidel<strong>in</strong>es as to how these risk factors could be chosen for measur<strong>in</strong>g marketrisk. For measur<strong>in</strong>g portfolio credit risk relative to a benchmark, on the


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 163EXHIBIT 9.5 <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures Under Migration Mode and Mult<strong>in</strong>ormalDistribution for Asset ReturnsDescription Portfolio Held (bp) Benchmark (bp) Active Portfolio (bp)%EL 27.1 34.0 7.0%UL 112.7 88.8 89.5%CrVaR 90% 85.2 102.9 38.6%ESR 90% 247.7 240.3 125.8other hand, there are no clear guidel<strong>in</strong>es as to what these risk factors shouldbe. As a result, there are no guid<strong>in</strong>g pr<strong>in</strong>ciples for best practices <strong>in</strong> report<strong>in</strong>gcredit risk. In this section, I present a credit risk report that would be astep <strong>in</strong> this direction.Earlier <strong>in</strong> this chapter, I argued why an approach based on track<strong>in</strong>gerror is not appropriate for measur<strong>in</strong>g the credit risk of a portfolio relativeto its benchmark. This led me to def<strong>in</strong>e the relative credit risk by sett<strong>in</strong>g upan active portfolio compris<strong>in</strong>g long and short positions <strong>in</strong> the bonds thatconstitute the benchmark. The nom<strong>in</strong>al exposures of the bonds <strong>in</strong> the activeportfolio are given by equation (9.1). The credit risk measures <strong>in</strong>troduced<strong>in</strong> earlier chapters can then be computed for all relevant portfolios. Toensure that the risk measures are comparable across portfolios, these shouldbe reported as a percentage of the market value of the portfolios. Exhibit9.5 shows a credit risk report that provides a comparison of various creditrisk measures evaluated for three portfolios: the portfolio held, the benchmarkportfolio, and the active portfolio.One can <strong>in</strong>fer from Exhibit 9.5 that the scope for underperformance isquite significant as <strong>in</strong>dicated by the risk measures computed for the activeportfolio. Notice that although the ESRs at 90 percent confidence level forthe portfolio held and the benchmark are very similar, the ESR for the activeportfolio is quite large. This can arise, for <strong>in</strong>stance, through rat<strong>in</strong>g upgradesfor some issuers held <strong>in</strong> the benchmark but not <strong>in</strong> the portfolio, whichresults <strong>in</strong> a difference <strong>in</strong> relative performance. Measur<strong>in</strong>g only the downsiderisks of the portfolio and benchmark <strong>in</strong>dependently does not capture therelative risk of underperformance between the two portfolios.The relative risk between the benchmark and the portfolio could be aresult of <strong>in</strong>tentional deviations taken by the portfolio manager. If this is notthe case, then identify<strong>in</strong>g the major sources that contribute to this risk isrequired to decide on suitable trades that can reduce this risk. This <strong>in</strong>formationcan be derived from the unexpected loss contribution report shown<strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.6. This exhibit identifies the exposure difference between theportfolio and the benchmark to a Ba2-rat<strong>in</strong>g grade be<strong>in</strong>g responsible for asignificant part of the risk. Alternatively, one can also attribute a significant


164 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 9.6Unexpected Loss Contributions to UL of Active PortfolioAcross Rat<strong>in</strong>gs Across Industries Across SectorsRat<strong>in</strong>g %ULC (bp) Industry %ULC (bp) Sector %ULC (bp)Aaa 0 BAC 3.7 Industrials 46.7Aa1 0 CCL 7.0 Utilities 5.3Aa2 0 CNC 3.6 F<strong>in</strong>ancials 37.6Aa3 0 COT 14.2A1 5.2 ENE 0A2 4.6 TRA 18.2A3 2.2 UTL 5.2Baa1 17.2 BNK 3.7Baa2 0 BRO 0Baa3 0 FIN 5.4Ba1 0 INR 28.5Ba2 34.9Ba3 7.3B1 18.2B2 0B3 0Caa–C 0part of this risk to the difference <strong>in</strong> exposure to the <strong>in</strong>surance and reits(INR) sector.Exhibit 9.7 exam<strong>in</strong>es the various credit risk measures under theassumption that the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns of obligors is multivariatet rather than mult<strong>in</strong>ormal. Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Exhibit 9.7, one can see thatthe relative credit risk has reduced marg<strong>in</strong>ally under the multivariate tassumption. This might appear surpris<strong>in</strong>g at a first glance. However, notethat under the multivariate t distribution there is greater tail dependencebetween the obligor asset returns. Hence, an extreme movement <strong>in</strong> assetreturns will be more correlated than that modeled by a mult<strong>in</strong>ormal distribution.This has the implication that the risk of an underperformance dueEXHIBIT 9.7 <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures Under Migration Mode and Multivariatet Distribution for Asset ReturnsDescription Portfolio Held (bp) Benchmark (bp) Active Portfolio (bp)%EL 27.1 34.0 7.0%UL 123.4 105.6 86.8%CrVaR 90% 79.5 96.6 33.8%ESR 90% 252.6 256.2 112.5


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 165EXHIBIT 9.8Unexpected Loss Contributions to UL of Active PortfolioAcross Rat<strong>in</strong>gs Across Industries Across SectorsRat<strong>in</strong>g %ULC (bp) Industry %ULC (bp) Sector %ULC (bp)Aaa 0 BAC 3.6 Industrials 46.3Aa1 0 CCL 7.0 Utilities 5.0Aa2 0 CNC 3.6 F<strong>in</strong>ancials 35.5Aa3 0 COT 13.9A1 4.9 ENE 0A2 4.4 TRA 18.3A3 2.1 UTL 5.0Baa1 16.3 BNK 3.4Baa2 0 BRO 0Baa3 0 FIN 5.0Ba1 0 INR 27.0Ba2 33.5Ba3 7.3B1 18.3B2 0B3 0Caa–C 0to exposure differences to various obligors <strong>in</strong> the portfolio and the benchmarkwill be less severe than that implied by the mult<strong>in</strong>ormal distribution.The unexpected loss contributions to the unexpected loss of the active portfoliofrom different credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs and <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors under the multivariatet distribution are shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.8.<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g Dur<strong>in</strong>g Economic ContractionsThe forego<strong>in</strong>g credit risk reports can be regarded as standard reports, whichare valid dur<strong>in</strong>g normal market conditions. This is because the recovery ratevalues and the rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix used to generate the risk reportreflect historical averages over many economic cycles. Dur<strong>in</strong>g period of economiccontraction, however, empirical evidence <strong>in</strong>dicates that the recoveryvalues are lower and rat<strong>in</strong>g downgrade and default probabilities are usuallyhigher than historical averages. Other stylized facts are an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> yieldspreads between rat<strong>in</strong>g categories and a greater asset return correlationbetween obligors dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of economic contraction.To adequately capture the risks under such market conditions, it isimportant to <strong>in</strong>clude risk reports generated by appropriately modify<strong>in</strong>g the<strong>in</strong>put parameters of the credit risk model. Interpreted differently, such


166Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa–C DefaultAaa 86.872 7.392 3.648 0.588 0.888 0.348 0.204 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.048 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.012Aa1 2.650 75.570 9.840 8.232 2.892 0.396 0.060 0.228 0.000 0.000 0.108 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.024Aa2 0.740 3.050 77.838 10.584 4.956 1.704 0.732 0.204 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.060 0.096 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.036Aa3 0.080 0.640 3.520 78.624 11.160 3.936 1.068 0.300 0.264 0.204 0.000 0.048 0.108 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.048A1 0.030 0.110 0.620 5.760 78.360 9.000 3.600 0.972 0.336 0.168 0.444 0.312 0.060 0.144 0.012 0.000 0.000 0.072A2 0.050 0.060 0.300 0.800 5.570 78.256 8.976 3.588 0.996 0.492 0.348 0.132 0.144 0.036 0.084 0.036 0.036 0.096A3 0.050 0.110 0.050 0.240 1.550 8.680 72.616 8.436 4.596 1.800 0.684 0.240 0.276 0.420 0.060 0.060 0.012 0.120Baa1 0.080 0.020 0.140 0.190 0.210 2.840 8.040 71.920 9.276 3.948 1.308 0.576 0.444 0.696 0.108 0.024 0.024 0.156Baa2 0.070 0.110 0.130 0.180 0.180 0.920 3.870 7.270 72.966 8.880 2.124 0.660 0.828 0.612 0.564 0.324 0.036 0.276Baa3 0.030 0.000 0.030 0.080 0.190 0.610 0.690 3.420 9.920 68.542 8.148 3.312 2.424 1.020 0.396 0.432 0.204 0.552Ba1 0.090 0.000 0.000 0.030 0.240 0.130 0.730 0.820 3.200 8.360 69.492 6.000 5.064 1.464 1.656 1.488 0.432 0.804Ba2 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.030 0.040 0.160 0.140 0.390 0.770 2.530 9.180 67.068 8.184 2.208 4.884 2.484 0.696 1.236Ba3 0.000 0.020 0.000 0.000 0.040 0.170 0.190 0.190 0.280 0.750 2.940 5.470 68.866 6.300 6.720 4.008 1.104 2.952B1 0.020 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.060 0.100 0.160 0.080 0.260 0.320 0.450 2.690 6.090 67.870 6.696 8.160 2.280 4.764B2 0.000 0.000 0.060 0.010 0.110 0.000 0.070 0.180 0.120 0.190 0.300 1.690 3.050 5.950 58.402 14.040 4.584 11.244B3 0.000 0.000 0.070 0.000 0.020 0.040 0.070 0.120 0.130 0.220 0.200 0.380 1.280 4.410 3.690 63.894 9.012 16.464Caa–C 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.540 0.540 0.710 0.000 1.520 2.060 1.370 3.200 54.540 35.520Default 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 100.00EXHIBIT 9.9 Modified 1-Year Rat<strong>in</strong>g Transition Matrix Under 20 Percent Stress Factor


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 167reports can be regarded as stress reports under adverse market conditions.Under such an <strong>in</strong>terpretation, the factor by which certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>put variables ofthe credit risk model are modified to reflect <strong>in</strong>creased risks aris<strong>in</strong>g from aweak economy can be referred to as the stress factor. In general, the groupresponsible for the risk report<strong>in</strong>g usually decides the appropriate stress factorsto be used. For purpose of illustration, I consider the stress factor hereto be 20 percent. Note that, <strong>in</strong> general, the stress factors do not have to bethe same for all <strong>in</strong>put variables.To generate the credit risk report under the 20 percent stress factor,the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>put variables to the credit risk model were changed asfollows:A decrease <strong>in</strong> the recovery rates by 20 percent from the historicalaverage.An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the yield spreads between rat<strong>in</strong>g categories by 20 percentfrom the values given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 5.8 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 5.An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the asset return correlation between obligor pairs by 20percent.An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the rat<strong>in</strong>g downgrade and default probabilities by 20percent.The normalized rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix under the 20 percent stress factoris shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.9. Note that the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the downgrade anddefault probabilities is assumed to occur at the expense of a lower probabilityof the obligor rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the same rat<strong>in</strong>g grade at the end of the1-year horizon.Exhibit 9.10 shows the credit risk measures generated with the20 percent stress factor under the migration mode and multivariatet-distribution assumption for asset returns. One can <strong>in</strong>fer from thisexhibit that there is a significant <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the credit risk measures forthe active portfolio, which suggests that the magnitude of underperformanceaga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark can be much greater under these marketconditions.EXHIBIT 9.10 <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures for 20 Percent Stress Factor Under MigrationMode and Multivariate t Distribution for Asset ReturnsDescription Portfolio Held (bp) Benchmark (bp) Active Portfolio (bp)%EL 38.8 47.2 8.5%UL 157.1 139.3 98.2%CVaR 90% 121.6 141.4 43.4%ESR 90% 348.9 356.7 141.5


168 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSPORTFOLIO MARKET RISK REPORTAlthough the major preoccupation here has been to measure and report thecredit risk of a corporate bond portfolio, present<strong>in</strong>g the market risk reportof the portfolio constitutes an <strong>in</strong>tegral part of the risk-report<strong>in</strong>g requirementfor a corporate bond portfolio. Reports for market risk are muchmore standardized <strong>in</strong> terms of what the appropriate risk quantities presentedshould be. Effective duration and effective convexity are almost standardrisk quantities that are presented <strong>in</strong> a market risk report. Track<strong>in</strong>g errordef<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Chapter 4 is also a standard risk measure that is presented. It isuseful to remark that duration provides an estimate of the potential loss <strong>in</strong>market value if the yield curve shifts up by 100 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. However, theprobability associated with such an event occurr<strong>in</strong>g is not known. Quantitiessuch as track<strong>in</strong>g error, value at risk, and expected shortfall risk, on theother hand, capture both the magnitude of potential underperformance andits associated probability.The tail risk measures for market risk also can be quantified if oneknows the shape of the return distribution aris<strong>in</strong>g from market risk. If onefollows standard practice, the distribution of returns driven by market riskcan be assumed to be normal. This <strong>in</strong>formation coupled with the knowledgeof the standard deviation of returns of the portfolio or the benchmark allowscomputation of the value at risk (VaR) and the expected shortfall risk aris<strong>in</strong>gfrom market risk at the desired confidence level. To compute VaR at the90 percent level of confidence, the standard deviation of the portfolio returnsgiven by equation (4.32) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 4 has to be scaled by the factor 1.28. Tocompute ESR at the 90 percent level of confidence, the appropriate scal<strong>in</strong>gfactor by which the standard deviation of portfolio returns has to be multipliedcan be determ<strong>in</strong>ed by solv<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tegral equation:q1l 1 0.9 1 x exp(0.5x 2 )dx221.28(9.6)Comput<strong>in</strong>g this <strong>in</strong>tegral gives the scal<strong>in</strong>g factor to be equal to 1.76.The relative tail risk measures can be computed by appropriately scal<strong>in</strong>gthe track<strong>in</strong>g error of the portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark. For <strong>in</strong>stance,to compute relative ESR at the 90 percent confidence level, one needs tomultiply the track<strong>in</strong>g error by 1.76. Divid<strong>in</strong>g the result<strong>in</strong>g figure by themarket value of the portfolio gives %ESR at the same confidence level.Exhibit 9.11 shows a typical market risk report for the corporate bondportfolio given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.1 managed aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark portfoliogiven <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.7 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 with the necessary drill-down capabilityto analyze the risks and the risk sources.


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 169EXHIBIT 9.11Market <strong>Risk</strong> ReportDescription Portfolio BenchmarkEffective yield (%) 5.55 5.58Effective duration 3.512 3.548Effective convexity 15.47 16.20%VaR (90% confidence level) (%) 3.37 3.41%ESR (90% confidence level) (%) 4.63 4.69Shift sensitivity (USD swap curve) (bp) 35.19 35.56Twist sensitivity (USD swap curve) (bp) 2.90 2.55Shift sensitivity (EUR swap curve) (bp) 0 0Twist sensitivity (EUR swap curve) (bp) 0 0Exchange rate sensitivity (bp) 0 0Implied yield volatility sensitivity (bp) 0 0Relative risk measuresTrack<strong>in</strong>g error (bp) 4.2%VaR (90% confidence level) (bp) 5.4%ESR (90% confidence level) (bp) 7.4In Exhibit 9.11, shift sensitivity refers to the risk sensitivity to a10-basis po<strong>in</strong>t parallel shift of the swap curve, twist sensitivity refers tothe risk sensitivity to a 10-basis po<strong>in</strong>t flatten<strong>in</strong>g of the swap curve,exchange rate sensitivity refers to the sensitivity to a 1 percent appreciationof any foreign currencies held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio relative to the basecurrency of the portfolio, and implied yield volatility sensitivity refers tothe sensitivity to a 1 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the implied yield volatility. Therisk model given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 4.4 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 4 was used to compute track<strong>in</strong>gerror and tail risk measures. It is useful to note that the relative riskmeasures for market risk are significantly lower than the relative riskmeasures for credit risk. This provides some justification for the focus byportfolio managers primarily on credit risk when manag<strong>in</strong>g a corporatebond portfolio.<strong>Risk</strong> Guidel<strong>in</strong>esSo far <strong>in</strong> this chapter, I have exam<strong>in</strong>ed how the market and credit risk of acorporate bond portfolio relative to a benchmark can be presented <strong>in</strong> a simpleand <strong>in</strong>tuitive manner such that the effectiveness of risk communicationbetween the portfolio manager and the client is improved. If the portfoliomanagement mandate explicitly stipulates that portfolio managers are permittedto take risks relative to the benchmark to add value, it is importantthat the level of relative risk permitted be agreed upon <strong>in</strong> advance. Such


170 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSagreements are laid down <strong>in</strong> the risk guidel<strong>in</strong>es document associated withthe portfolio management mandate. <strong>Risk</strong> guidel<strong>in</strong>es are meant to ensurethat the client is aware of potential deviations <strong>in</strong> return between the portfolioand the benchmark that can occur as a result of deviat<strong>in</strong>g from thebenchmark-neutral positions.The risk guidel<strong>in</strong>es document can be quite detailed <strong>in</strong> terms of thepermissible size of each bond that can be held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio, the maximumnom<strong>in</strong>al amount of a bond that can be purchased relative to itsissue size, the permissible leverage, and the unhedged foreign currencyexposure that can be held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. Because these risk guidel<strong>in</strong>esare imposed on directly observable quantities, monitor<strong>in</strong>g them is ratherstraightforward. Much more difficult risk guidel<strong>in</strong>es to agree upon andsubsequently monitor are those that are imposed on the relative riskbetween the portfolio and the benchmark. In particular, for corporatebond portfolios there are no standards currently available to guide thechoice of the relative risk measures and to impose mean<strong>in</strong>gful limits onthem. As a result, identify<strong>in</strong>g an appropriate relative risk measure andimpos<strong>in</strong>g limits on permissible exposures becomes a rather lengthy consultationprocess.Follow<strong>in</strong>g the discussion so far <strong>in</strong> this chapter, it is clear that relativerisk exposures for a corporate portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st its benchmark need to bedef<strong>in</strong>ed separately for market risk and credit risk. In this connection, therisk reports presented <strong>in</strong> this chapter provide useful risk measures forwhich permissible limits can be enforced when a portfolio managementmandate is awarded. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the risk guidel<strong>in</strong>e can explicitly statethat the percentage expected shortfall risk at 90 percent confidence levelfor the active portfolio should not exceed 200 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. Monitor<strong>in</strong>gsuch risk limits will be easy if the risk report<strong>in</strong>g framework presented hereis adopted.PERFORMANCE ATTRIBUTIONOver any report<strong>in</strong>g period, <strong>in</strong>vestors compare the performance of theirportfolio mandates relative to the benchmark. In order to judge the<strong>in</strong>vestment performance of the portfolio manager, one tries to identifythe good and bad allocation decisions that led to the out- or underperformanceaga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark. This process, which is usually referredto as performance attribution, is a method for attribut<strong>in</strong>g the valueadded aris<strong>in</strong>g from the <strong>in</strong>vestment management decisions so that boththe <strong>in</strong>vestment manager and the client are aware of the sources of thisvalue added. Such a report not only helps to <strong>in</strong>crease the transparency ofthe <strong>in</strong>vestment process from the client’s perspective, but also allows for


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 171more discipl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>vestment decisions by portfolio managers. A performanceattribution report is most useful from the <strong>in</strong>vestment manager’sperspective if the <strong>in</strong>vestment management process is well <strong>in</strong>tegrated<strong>in</strong>to the report so that the value added as a result of the <strong>in</strong>vestment decisionsis clearly identifiable. This allows the <strong>in</strong>vestment manager to communicatethe <strong>in</strong>vestment management process more effectively to theclient and to attribute the value added result<strong>in</strong>g from the <strong>in</strong>vestmentdecisions.Standard techniques for performance attribution seek to identify thevalue added result<strong>in</strong>g from exposures to specific risk factors that model the<strong>in</strong>herent risks <strong>in</strong> a portfolio. 2 Such risk factors are usually chosen to modelthe <strong>in</strong>vestment styles of portfolio managers so that the <strong>in</strong>vestment decisionprocess will be captured <strong>in</strong> the attribution report. For <strong>in</strong>stance, fixed<strong>in</strong>comeportfolio managers implement their view on changes to the level of<strong>in</strong>terest rates by tak<strong>in</strong>g an active duration bet aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark. Suchactive duration bets could result <strong>in</strong> a risk exposure to the parallel shift ofthe yield curve. In other <strong>in</strong>stances, portfolio managers may implementviews held on the evolution of the shape of the yield curve by overweight<strong>in</strong>gor underweight<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> yield curve sectors relative to the benchmark.Such a market view, if implemented, would result <strong>in</strong> an active curve twistexposure. In this manner, one can identify a set of aggregate risk exposuresrelative to the benchmark that result from conscious <strong>in</strong>vestment decisions.The purpose of the performance attribution report is to attribute the excessreturn aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark to each of the aggregate risk factors and bydo<strong>in</strong>g this, help improve the transparency of the <strong>in</strong>vestment managementprocess.The forego<strong>in</strong>g factor exposures are ma<strong>in</strong>ly representative of highgradefixed-<strong>in</strong>come portfolios made up of government bonds or bondsissued by agencies and supranational <strong>in</strong>stitutions. This is because themajor sources of risk <strong>in</strong> such portfolios result from exposure to marketrisk, and the factors just mentioned model market risk. For a portfoliocompris<strong>in</strong>g corporate bonds, the dom<strong>in</strong>ant risk is credit risk. As a result,<strong>in</strong>vestment styles of corporate bond portfolio managers differ from thoseof a traditional government bond portfolio manager. The value addedaga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark <strong>in</strong> corporate bond portfolios results primarily fromtak<strong>in</strong>g a view on the corporate borrowers creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess and correspond<strong>in</strong>glyunderweight<strong>in</strong>g or overweight<strong>in</strong>g the exposures to specificissuer names. In this connection, it is tempt<strong>in</strong>g to argue that corporatebond portfolio management has much <strong>in</strong> common with equity portfoliomanagement. In reality, there are substantial differences between the twowhen it comes to <strong>in</strong>vestment styles. To outperform the benchmark, equityportfolio managers try to pick “w<strong>in</strong>ners” and avoid “losers.” <strong>Corporate</strong>bond portfolio managers, on the other hand, focus primarily on avoid<strong>in</strong>g


172 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS“losers.” This is because the upside potential on bonds is usually limited,but the downside risk is substantial.Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g the differences, it is helpful to review the performanceattribution practices <strong>in</strong> equity portfolio management. One popular technique<strong>in</strong> equity portfolio management is to perform style analysis, whichrequires break<strong>in</strong>g a broad <strong>in</strong>dex down <strong>in</strong>to several mutually exclusive componentssuch as large and small caps and value and growth segments. Astyle analysis model then aims to quantify the exposures of a portfolio tothe various style factors. Excess returns aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark are thenattributed to different style factors based on the exposures held to these factorsdur<strong>in</strong>g the performance attribution period.This style analysis, though not directly applicable to corporate bondportfolios, is an appeal<strong>in</strong>g technique for attribut<strong>in</strong>g performance. For<strong>in</strong>stance, corporate bond portfolio managers try to add value by identify<strong>in</strong>gpromis<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors and overweight<strong>in</strong>g those sectors. Furthermore,because the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the issuers <strong>in</strong>fluences yield spreads, the relativeexposure to different credit rat<strong>in</strong>g categories is also an active <strong>in</strong>vestmentdecision criterion. Tak<strong>in</strong>g both these aspects <strong>in</strong>to account, I now <strong>in</strong>dicatehow a performance attribution model can be developed for corporate bondportfolios.A Simple Attribution ModelIn an active portfolio management mandate, portfolio managers pursuedifferent <strong>in</strong>vestment strategies that offer the prospect of add<strong>in</strong>g valueaga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark. Ex post, portfolio managers are <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong>know<strong>in</strong>g how well their <strong>in</strong>vestment strategies performed and what tradeswere most successful <strong>in</strong> terms of add<strong>in</strong>g value. Moreover, client-report<strong>in</strong>grequirements may even state that the factors that contributed to under- oroutperformance aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark be clearly identified. The identifiedfactors should relate to <strong>in</strong>vestment styles pursued so that the <strong>in</strong>vestmentprocess is well <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong> the attribution report. In this section, Idevelop a simple model for attribut<strong>in</strong>g the excess returns aga<strong>in</strong>st thebenchmark. The approach is to attribute the excess returns aga<strong>in</strong>st thebenchmark to two major components: (a) the relevant style factors and(b) security selection with<strong>in</strong> the style factors. The details are given <strong>in</strong> whatfollows.The first step <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g an attribution model is to identify the relevantstyle factors to which the return will be attributed. I mentioned thatthe issuer credit rat<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>in</strong>dustry sector are factors that <strong>in</strong>fluence the<strong>in</strong>vestment decisions. In this case, a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of these attributes canserve as a suitable style factor for performance attribution. Specifically,


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 173consider group<strong>in</strong>g the various credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong>to three buckets compris<strong>in</strong>gissuers rated Aa or higher, A-rated issuers, and Baa and lower rated issuers.Furthermore, let the <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors be broadly classified <strong>in</strong>to f<strong>in</strong>ancials,<strong>in</strong>dustrials, and utilities. Such a categorization results <strong>in</strong> n<strong>in</strong>e mutuallyexclusive factors, each of which is a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g and<strong>in</strong>dustry sector. For <strong>in</strong>stance, all A-rated issuers belong<strong>in</strong>g to the f<strong>in</strong>ancialsector constitute one style factor for the return attribution model. In practice,one could <strong>in</strong>crease the number of <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors <strong>in</strong> the attributionmodel to <strong>in</strong>clude more style factors.Once the relevant style factors for the performance attribution modelhave been determ<strong>in</strong>ed, the attribution process requires identify<strong>in</strong>g benchmarkand portfolio exposures to each of these style factors. Know<strong>in</strong>g theexposure weights to the style factors and the returns associated with eachstyle factor, one can attribute excess returns to these style factors. Theexcess returns generated by security selection with<strong>in</strong> the style factors arethen identified. The mathematical details of the attribution process are asfollows.Without loss of generality, I assume that the number of bonds <strong>in</strong> thebenchmark and the portfolio are identical. Under this assumption, theweights for some or many of the bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio are zero. <strong>Bond</strong>s withzero weights <strong>in</strong> the benchmark <strong>in</strong>dicate that they are not part of the benchmarkbut are held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. The return attribution model to be developedhere uses the follow<strong>in</strong>g notations:w k B,i Weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the benchmark that is grouped underthe kth style factor.w k P,i Weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio that is grouped under thekth style factor.N k Number of bonds that are grouped under the kth style factor.S Number of style factors modeled.w k B Sum of the weights of all bonds <strong>in</strong> the benchmark grouped underthe kth style factor.w k P Sum of the weights of all bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio grouped underthe kth style factor.r k i Return over the <strong>in</strong>vestment period of the ith bond grouped underthe kth style factor (<strong>in</strong>cludes price return and accrued <strong>in</strong>terest).R k B Total return over the <strong>in</strong>vestment period from all bonds <strong>in</strong> thebenchmark grouped under the kth style factor.R k P Total return over the <strong>in</strong>vestment period from all bonds <strong>in</strong> theportfolio grouped under the kth style factor.R B Return over the <strong>in</strong>vestment period of the benchmark.R P Return over the <strong>in</strong>vestment period of the portfolio.


174 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSIt is easy to show that the follow<strong>in</strong>g relations hold:w k B aN kw k P aN kR k B aN kR B aSSa wB k 1k1wB,iki1wP,iki1i1R k Bk1w k B,i r kiThe ma<strong>in</strong> goal of the attribution model is to allocate the excess returnof the portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark to two components: The excessreturns as a result of different exposures held to style factors and the excessreturns to the specific choice of the securities with<strong>in</strong> each style factor.The portfolio return result<strong>in</strong>g from the exposure to the kth style factoris a function of the relative weight of the portfolio to this style factor <strong>in</strong> relationto the benchmark weights and is given byR k P wk P R kwBk B(9.7)The excess return attributed to the kth style factor is then the follow<strong>in</strong>g:R k style R k P R k B,k 1,...,S(9.8)The excess return attributed to security selection with<strong>in</strong> the kth style factoris given byN kR k security a w k P,i r k i R k P,i1k 1,...,S(9.9)Excess return that is not attributed either to the style factor or to securityselection forms the residual return. This is given bySSR residual R P R B a R k style aR k securityk1k1(9.10)


<strong>Risk</strong> Report<strong>in</strong>g and Performance Attribution 175EXHIBIT 9.12Attribution of Excess Returns Over Investment Period<strong>Bond</strong> Total Benchmark Portfolio Style R k B R k P R k style R k securityReturn (%) Weight (%) Weight (%) Factor (%) (%) (%) (%)1.0 10 30 Factor 1 0.50 0.50 0.00 0.202.0 20 0 Factor 11.5 30 0 Factor 2 0.95 0.57 0.38 0.182.5 20 30 Factor 20.5 10 0 Factor 3 0.17 0.34 0.17 0.141.2 10 40 Factor 3The attribution model developed here is best illustrated with the help of anumerical example. Specifically, consider the benchmark to comprise sixbonds with three style factors and the portfolio to be <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> threebonds of the six <strong>in</strong> the benchmark. The active strategy pursued results <strong>in</strong> anunderperformance of 9 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. Exhibit 9.12, which is self-explanatory,attributes the return difference versus the benchmark to various style factorsand to security selection with<strong>in</strong> the style factors on the basis of themodel developed here.QUESTIONS1. What are the important attributes of a good risk report?2. What is the standard risk measure used to quantify the relative risk ofa portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st a benchmark? What are the drawbacks of us<strong>in</strong>gsuch a risk measure to quantify portfolio credit risk relative to itsbenchmark?3. How is relative credit risk def<strong>in</strong>ed? What are the measures used toquantify relative credit risk?4. What are the advantages of the relative credit risk measures <strong>in</strong>troducedhere compared to other relative risk measures commonly used?5. How is marg<strong>in</strong>al risk contribution def<strong>in</strong>ed? Show that the expected losscontribution of <strong>in</strong>dividual bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio add up to the unexpectedloss of the portfolio.6. For the example portfolio considered <strong>in</strong> this chapter, the relative tail riskmeasures were lower when the jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns wasmodeled to be multivariate t distributed. Justify why this is the case.7. Under the multivariate t-distribution assumption for asset returns, willthe absolute credit risk measures of the portfolio be higher or lowerthan those computed under the mult<strong>in</strong>ormal distribution assumptionfor asset returns? Justify your answer.


176 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS8. If you were a portfolio manager, what are the various risk reports youwould want to send to your clients?9. To compute ESR for market risk at the 95 percent level of confidence,what is the appropriate scal<strong>in</strong>g factor to be used <strong>in</strong> conjunction withthe track<strong>in</strong>g error of the portfolio? Assume excess returns result<strong>in</strong>gfrom market risk are normally distributed.10. What is the difference between performance attribution and risk attribution?What purpose does a performance attribution report serve?11. What are the important risk factors to which performance is attributed<strong>in</strong> a high-grade government bond portfolio? Is it appropriate to use thesame factors for attribut<strong>in</strong>g the performance of corporate bond portfolios?Justify your answer.12. For a corporate bond portfolio, what are the relevant factors to whichone can attribute performance?


CHAPTER 10Portfolio OptimizationSo far <strong>in</strong> this book, I have exam<strong>in</strong>ed how market and credit risk can bequantified and how the relative risk measures versus a given benchmarkcan be computed. Depend<strong>in</strong>g on the nature of the portfolio managementmandate, the relative risks versus the benchmark may either be permittedor need to be elim<strong>in</strong>ated to the extent possible. Elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g all risks aga<strong>in</strong>sta given benchmark is almost impossible <strong>in</strong> most practical situations. Therefore,the task of a portfolio manager will be to ensure that the relative riskis kept to a m<strong>in</strong>imum, or <strong>in</strong> those cases where it is permitted, to take thoserisks that offer scope for <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the expected excess returns versus thebenchmark. In addition to this, the portfolio manager will have to rebalancethe portfolio once every month or once every quarter to ensure thatthe risk characteristics are replicated when the benchmark compositionchanges. Perform<strong>in</strong>g these tasks would be simplified if tools for portfolioselection were available to help guide the risk-tak<strong>in</strong>g, rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g, andportfolio construction processes. In situations where the benchmark comprisesseveral hundred bond issuers, perform<strong>in</strong>g a proper credit analysis ofall the issuers may itself be a very laborious process. Access to portfoliooptimization tools <strong>in</strong> such cases would be of valuable help to portfoliomanagers.In this chapter, I <strong>in</strong>troduce techniques for portfolio optimization thatachieve the forego<strong>in</strong>g objectives. First, I provide some background <strong>in</strong>formationon bond portfolio optimization and argue why a quantitativeapproach to the selection of a corporate bond portfolio can be attractive.This is followed by a brief review of optimization methods and subsequentlya discussion on the practical difficulties that can arise when us<strong>in</strong>goptimization techniques for portfolio selection. I then present differentways to formulate an optimization problem for portfolio construction andportfolio rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g. In the f<strong>in</strong>al section, I demonstrate the impact modelparameters have on the optimal portfolio composition by tak<strong>in</strong>g a marketcapitalization weighted corporate bond benchmark.177


178 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSPORTFOLIO SELECTION TECHNIQUESWhen performance of a bond portfolio is measured relative to a benchmark,a major concern of the portfolio manager is which bonds to hold <strong>in</strong>the portfolio. If the benchmark <strong>in</strong>cludes only government bonds or Aaaratedbonds, the portfolio selection problem becomes rather simple.Because the major risks among high-grade issuers is primarily systematicrisk, the bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio need to be selected such that the systematicrisk factors are hedged. The systematic risk factors for high-grade bondissuers arise from shape changes to the yield curve, which can be capturedus<strong>in</strong>g two or three risk factors. Typically, five or six bonds can replicate thesystematic risk factors of a benchmark compris<strong>in</strong>g government bonds orAaa-rated bonds. Choos<strong>in</strong>g the appropriate bonds to replicate the systematicrisk factors <strong>in</strong> such cases is a trivial exercise for a portfolio manager.Extend<strong>in</strong>g the portfolio selection technique to the case where thebenchmark is a global government bond benchmark is also quite straightforward.In this case, one can construct a risk model compris<strong>in</strong>g the systematicrisk factors for every government bond market and then select aportfolio that m<strong>in</strong>imizes the track<strong>in</strong>g error between the portfolio and thebenchmark. Choos<strong>in</strong>g portfolios to replicate a multicurrency governmentbond benchmark through track<strong>in</strong>g error m<strong>in</strong>imization is a standard toolmost software vendors for fixed-<strong>in</strong>come analytics provide.Now consider the problem of select<strong>in</strong>g a portfolio to replicate a benchmarkcompris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bonds. Traditional approachesto address<strong>in</strong>g this problem follow a technique popularly known as thecell-<strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>g strategy. In simple terms, the cell-<strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>g strategy requiresidentify<strong>in</strong>g different risk attributes for an <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade bond benchmarkand then select<strong>in</strong>g bonds that replicate each of these risk attributes.Specifically, one may identify the risk attributes to broadly <strong>in</strong>clude bondmaturity, <strong>in</strong>dustry sector, and rat<strong>in</strong>g category. If, for <strong>in</strong>stance, one divideseach of these risk categories <strong>in</strong>to three further subcategories, then any bond<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade benchmark can be assigned to 1 of 27 possible riskbuckets or cells. For purpose of illustration, th<strong>in</strong>k of the maturity of bondsbelong<strong>in</strong>g to the 1- to 5-year sector, the 5- to 10-year sector, or the greaterthan 10-year sector. Similarly, one could identify the <strong>in</strong>dustry sector thebond belongs to as be<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>dustrial sector, the f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector, or theutilities sector. The credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the bond can be identified as be<strong>in</strong>g Baa,A, or Aa and higher rat<strong>in</strong>g.Once the bonds <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade benchmark have been assignedto 1 of the 27 cells, portfolio replication becomes simply a task of choos<strong>in</strong>gbonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio such that they have the same allocation weights asthe benchmark to each cell. The drawback of this traditional approach isthat the portfolio constructed us<strong>in</strong>g the cell-<strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>g strategy will replicate


Portfolio Optimization 179only the systematic risk factors, 27 of which have been identified <strong>in</strong> theexample cited here. Issuer-specific risk, which constitutes the dom<strong>in</strong>ant partof the risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfolio, will not be hedged us<strong>in</strong>g the cell<strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>gstrategy.Another way of look<strong>in</strong>g at the cell-<strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>g approach is that it m<strong>in</strong>imizesthe track<strong>in</strong>g error aris<strong>in</strong>g from the exposure to the risk factors correspond<strong>in</strong>gto each cell. However, track<strong>in</strong>g error is not a suitable measure for captur<strong>in</strong>gthe issuer-specific risk or, equivalently, the credit risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate portfolioas argued <strong>in</strong> Chapter 9. This suggests that one has to formulate the portfolioselection problem to replicate the risk profile of a corporate bond benchmarkdifferently.Benefits of a Quantitative ApproachThe forego<strong>in</strong>g portfolio selection techniques can be regarded as quantitativeapproaches to portfolio construction. One may wonder at this po<strong>in</strong>t whythere is a need to follow a quantitative approach to select a corporate bondportfolio. In fact, some portfolio managers may be tempted to argue that ifadd<strong>in</strong>g value relative to a benchmark requires identify<strong>in</strong>g “good credits,”human judgment can be superior to a quantitative approach. In reality, however,most experienced portfolio managers know that differentiat<strong>in</strong>g goodcredits from bad credits is far from be<strong>in</strong>g a trivial exercise. Moreover, whenthe number of issuers <strong>in</strong> the benchmark is large, it is practically impossibleto do a thorough credit analysis of all bond issuers. In general, the costs<strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> carry<strong>in</strong>g out a credit analysis of a large number of issuers can beprohibitively high. In such cases, use of quantitative tools to identify potentialissuers to be <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the bond portfolio can be of much help.Another advantage of follow<strong>in</strong>g a quantitative approach to portfolioselection is that the risks at the portfolio level can be analyzed directlyrather than at the bond level. This allows one to construct a portfolio thatexhibits certa<strong>in</strong> desirable risk–return characteristics, which is then subjectto review by the portfolio manager.Other <strong>in</strong>stances where a quantitative approach to portfolio selection isattractive are when the size of the portfolio is large (typically several billions)or the <strong>in</strong>tention is to simply replicate the risk–return characteristicsof the benchmark for an <strong>in</strong>dexed portfolio mandate. For large portfoliosizes, levels of market exposure are too great to hold significant overweightpositions <strong>in</strong> a small number of bonds. Hence, such portfolios tend to bemore closely aligned to the benchmark composition.Construct<strong>in</strong>g a portfolio that matches the benchmark compositionclosely is, however, not a practical alternative either. Reasons for this arethat this approach usually leads to odd lot transactions, which are quiteexpensive, and that many older bond issues may be illiquid with regard to


180 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOStransactions. These considerations suggest that the replicat<strong>in</strong>g portfolio willoften <strong>in</strong>clude only a subset of the bonds <strong>in</strong> the benchmark. Identify<strong>in</strong>g sucha subset of bonds us<strong>in</strong>g quantitative methods is the only viable alternativeat least <strong>in</strong> cases where the portfolio management fees do not justify ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ga large credit research team.OPTIMIZATION METHODSMost readers are familiar with the theory of portfolio optimization <strong>in</strong> thecontext of select<strong>in</strong>g stock portfolios that exhibit certa<strong>in</strong> desirablerisk–return tradeoffs. Portfolio optimization theory deals with the processof identify<strong>in</strong>g the best portfolio composition from a collection of alternativesthat meet certa<strong>in</strong> desired risk–return tradeoffs without hav<strong>in</strong>g toexplicitly enumerate and evaluate all possible alternatives. The complexityof the process <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> identify<strong>in</strong>g the optimal candidate portfoliodepends on the optimization problem formulation.In broad terms, an optimization problem can be classified as either al<strong>in</strong>ear or a nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problem. A special case of a nonl<strong>in</strong>earprogramm<strong>in</strong>g problem arises if the objective function is a quadratic <strong>in</strong> thedesign variables and all the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions are l<strong>in</strong>ear. Such an optimizationproblem is referred to as a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem. Thestandard portfolio optimization problem based on the Markowitz theoryresults <strong>in</strong> a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem. In general, good problem formulationis the key to f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g solutions to an optimization problem that areuseful <strong>in</strong> practice. This skill is usually learned through practice and theknowledge of the strengths, weaknesses, and peculiarities of the solutionsobta<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g optimization theory.In this section, I discuss different optimization problem formulationsand the associated complexities <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the optimal solutionwith reference to the bond portfolio selection problem. Before proceed<strong>in</strong>gto do this, it is necessary to <strong>in</strong>troduce some terms commonly used <strong>in</strong> optimizationtheory. A feasible solution to an optimization problem is a solutionvector that satisfies all the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions. The set of all feasiblesolutions to an optimization problem is referred to as the feasible region.An optimal solution to a m<strong>in</strong>imization problem requires f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g a feasiblesolution that m<strong>in</strong>imizes the objective function value.L<strong>in</strong>ear Programm<strong>in</strong>gAs the name suggests, l<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problems def<strong>in</strong>e a particularclass of optimization problems <strong>in</strong> which both the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions andthe objective function are l<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>in</strong> the design variables. The design variables<strong>in</strong> the context of the bond portfolio selection problem are the relative


Portfolio Optimization 181weights of the <strong>in</strong>dividual bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g characteristicof l<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problems is that if an optimal solution exists,then at least one of the corner po<strong>in</strong>ts of the feasible region will qualify tobe an optimal solution. This property ensures that we need to exam<strong>in</strong>e onlya f<strong>in</strong>ite set of corner po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> the feasible region to f<strong>in</strong>d the optimal solution.As a result, algorithms for solv<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problems arevery efficient even when the number of design variables is several thousand.The computational efficiency of l<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problems makes itattractive to formulate the bond portfolio selection problem as a l<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>gproblem. However, if the objective is to f<strong>in</strong>d a tradeoff betweenthe relative risk of the portfolio versus the benchmark and the expectedexcess return, such a problem formulation is not feasible. This is becausethe portfolio risk is not l<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>in</strong> the relative weights of the <strong>in</strong>dividual bonds<strong>in</strong> the portfolio, which happen to be the design variables <strong>in</strong> this case.Quadratic Programm<strong>in</strong>gA quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem is an optimization problem <strong>in</strong> which theobjective function is quadratic and all the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions are l<strong>in</strong>ear.Most standard portfolio selection problems are formulated <strong>in</strong> this framework.Formulat<strong>in</strong>g the portfolio selection problem as a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>gproblem is attractive because computationally efficient methods existto solve the optimization problem when the objective function is convex. Insuch cases, a global m<strong>in</strong>imum to the optimization problem can be found.A quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem can be stated to have the follow<strong>in</strong>ggeneral form:M<strong>in</strong>imize x T Qx 2c T x, x H R nsubject tol e x Ax f uHere, Q is a n n matrix and A is a m n matrix of l<strong>in</strong>ear constra<strong>in</strong>t functions.The complexity of solv<strong>in</strong>g quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problems dependson the nature of the Q matrix. If Q is a positive-semidef<strong>in</strong>ite matrix (alleigenvalues are non-negative), efficient algorithms can be designed to solvethe optimization problem.Nonl<strong>in</strong>ear Programm<strong>in</strong>gAny optimization problem that cannot be classified <strong>in</strong>to a l<strong>in</strong>ear or a quadraticprogramm<strong>in</strong>g problem is classified under the category of a nonl<strong>in</strong>earprogramm<strong>in</strong>g problem. For <strong>in</strong>stance, if the objective function is l<strong>in</strong>ear but


182 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSsome of the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions are nonl<strong>in</strong>ear, then the optimization problemis classified as a nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problem. Solv<strong>in</strong>g nonl<strong>in</strong>earprogramm<strong>in</strong>g problems is more difficult and the complexity <strong>in</strong>creases considerablyas the number of design variables <strong>in</strong>creases. Although a variety ofmethods exists to solve nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problems, no s<strong>in</strong>gle methodis suitable for all types of problems. Certa<strong>in</strong> methods are more efficient thanothers <strong>in</strong> solv<strong>in</strong>g particular classes of nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problems.A major challenge <strong>in</strong> solv<strong>in</strong>g nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problems is thatthese problems exhibit local m<strong>in</strong>ima, and hence f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the global m<strong>in</strong>imumis difficult. The <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> computational complexity arises primarily fromthe fact that the global m<strong>in</strong>imum will be <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terior of the feasible regionrather than on the boundaries as <strong>in</strong> the case of l<strong>in</strong>ear and quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>gproblems.An analogy would help here to expla<strong>in</strong> the differences between the differentprogramm<strong>in</strong>g problems. If one relates the optimization problem tothe process of identify<strong>in</strong>g where a needle is hidden <strong>in</strong> a haystack, a l<strong>in</strong>earprogramm<strong>in</strong>g problem would only require look<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the eight cornerpo<strong>in</strong>ts of the haystack to f<strong>in</strong>d the needle. A quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problemwould require that we explore the entire outer surface of the haystackto f<strong>in</strong>d the needle. A nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problem, on the other hand,would necessitate exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the entire haystack because the needle couldbe hidden anywhere <strong>in</strong>side it.When formulat<strong>in</strong>g the optimization problem to select replicat<strong>in</strong>g bondportfolios, one should try to restrict the problem to be either a l<strong>in</strong>ear or aquadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem. This makes it computationally tractable<strong>in</strong> the face of the large number of design variables that are bound to arise<strong>in</strong> a practical sett<strong>in</strong>g.PRACTICAL DIFFICULTIESIn the previous section, I <strong>in</strong>dicated the computational difficulties <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g solutions to different types of optimization problems. In most practicalsituations, however, standard software libraries can be used to f<strong>in</strong>d theoptimal portfolio composition. The major concern when follow<strong>in</strong>g a quantitativeapproach to construct<strong>in</strong>g and rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond portfolioto replicate a given benchmark is then to question the implementability ofthe optimal portfolio composition <strong>in</strong> a practical sett<strong>in</strong>g. In other words, isthe optimal portfolio composition mean<strong>in</strong>gful to hold after tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>toaccount the transaction costs <strong>in</strong>volved? If the answer to this question is no,f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g an optimal portfolio turns out to be simply an academic exercise.To provide a concrete example, take the case of a portfolio managerwho holds a corporate bond portfolio. Imag<strong>in</strong>e that the portfolio manager


Portfolio Optimization 183has to re<strong>in</strong>vest cash <strong>in</strong>jections and simultaneously rebalance the portfoliobecause the benchmark composition has changed at the end of the month.The task of the portfolio manager is to buy and sell some bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolioso as to meet the objective of replicat<strong>in</strong>g the benchmark risk–returncharacteristics. Of <strong>in</strong>terest is whether an optimization problem can be formulatedto identify the bonds to buy and sell to meet the portfolio manager’sobjective. Unfortunately, the solutions provided by many standard optimizationproblem formulations require a significant amount of transactionsto be done. In most cases, the portfolio manager will ignore these solutionsbecause the transaction costs <strong>in</strong>volved will render the optimal portfoliocomposition unattractive to hold. In other <strong>in</strong>stances, the optimal portfoliocomposition may not be a feasible portfolio to hold because many of thebonds could be illiquid.At this stage, it is important to recognize that the optimal portfolio compositionis a manifestation of the objectives and constra<strong>in</strong>ts expressed <strong>in</strong> formulat<strong>in</strong>gthe portfolio selection problem. If transaction costs are not modeled<strong>in</strong> the problem formulation, the optimal portfolio composition could be verydifferent from the portfolio be<strong>in</strong>g held. Even assum<strong>in</strong>g that one imposes aconstra<strong>in</strong>t on the maximum turnover when portfolio rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g is done, theoptimal portfolio composition may require buy<strong>in</strong>g and sell<strong>in</strong>g many bondswhose transaction volumes are small. Such trade recommendations will alsobe rejected by portfolio managers due to the higher transaction cost <strong>in</strong>volved<strong>in</strong> trad<strong>in</strong>g small lot sizes and the risk of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g operational errors due tothe large number of transactions. Enforc<strong>in</strong>g explicit constra<strong>in</strong>ts on the numberof transactions is usually difficult, though not impossible.F<strong>in</strong>ally, it is important to realize that the notion of an optimal portfoliois rather subjective. It is subjective from the po<strong>in</strong>t of view that the optimalportfolio composition offers the best tradeoff for the given objective functionand set of constra<strong>in</strong>ts under certa<strong>in</strong> choices for the <strong>in</strong>put parameters ofthe model. If one modifies the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions of the optimization problem,one might well end up with a very different optimal portfolio composition.Hence, optimization tools should be used primarily as an aid to portfolioselection and to provide trade suggestions to the portfolio manager. Inthe rest of the chapter, I discuss different ways <strong>in</strong> which the optimal bondportfolio selection problem can be formulated <strong>in</strong> order to meet differentobjectives and constra<strong>in</strong>ts that the portfolio manager may wish to express.PORTFOLIO CONSTRUCTIONAssum<strong>in</strong>g that a portfolio management mandate has been awarded, thefirst step <strong>in</strong> the portfolio management process is to construct a portfoliothat replicates the risk–return characteristics of the benchmark. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the


184 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSportfolio construction process, one is usually <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> select<strong>in</strong>g a limitednumber of bonds that replicate the benchmark characteristics. Standardportfolio construction approaches consider m<strong>in</strong>imiz<strong>in</strong>g the track<strong>in</strong>g error ofthe portfolio versus the benchmark when select<strong>in</strong>g a replicat<strong>in</strong>g portfolio.With respect to a corporate bond portfolio, the track<strong>in</strong>g error m<strong>in</strong>imizationapproach can be regarded as the m<strong>in</strong>imization of the unexpected loss of theactive portfolio.However, adopt<strong>in</strong>g this approach will not be very useful <strong>in</strong> the presentcase. This is because such a problem formulation will lead to a portfoliowhose composition is identical to that of the benchmark. To see why this isthe case, recall that there is no notion of risk factors <strong>in</strong> a credit risk modelas is commonly the case with market risk. For credit risk, every obligor <strong>in</strong>the benchmark qualifies to be a risk factor. Clearly, if the objective functiontries to m<strong>in</strong>imize the unexpected loss of the active portfolio whose nom<strong>in</strong>alexposures are given by equation (9.1) <strong>in</strong> Chapter 9, then one will obta<strong>in</strong> aportfolio composition identical to the benchmark composition. Under thiscase, the unexpected loss of the active portfolio will be zero. Hence, formulat<strong>in</strong>gthe portfolio construction problem as unexpected loss m<strong>in</strong>imizationof the active portfolio will not give an implementable portfolio undermost circumstances.To formulate an optimization problem that will lead to an implementableportfolio, I briefly review how an optimal portfolio <strong>in</strong> the equitiesmarket is selected. In the context of an equity portfolio, all risks are classifiedunder market risk, which <strong>in</strong> turn is expressed through the volatility ofequity returns. For a given level of market risk, the portfolio that has thehighest expected return is considered to be the most efficient portfolio tohold. Such a portfolio can be selected by formulat<strong>in</strong>g a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>gproblem. This problem formulation is referred to as the mean-varianceoptimization problem <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ance.The conceptual framework for select<strong>in</strong>g an efficient portfolio <strong>in</strong> theequities market can be easily extended to the case of the corporate bondportfolio selection problem. In mak<strong>in</strong>g this extension, it is important torealize that corporate bonds have both market and credit risk. Hence, onemust consider both sources of risk when identify<strong>in</strong>g corporate bond portfoliosthat are more efficient than others. One could argue that corporatebond portfolio A is more efficient than portfolio B if both portfolios havethe same market risk and expected return but portfolio A has lower creditrisk. Stated differently, portfolio A is more efficient than portfolio B if therisk-adjusted return of portfolio A is higher. In the present case, portfolio Bcorresponds to the benchmark portfolio.Introduc<strong>in</strong>g the notion of efficient portfolio makes it possible to formulatethe optimal portfolio selection problem. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the credit riskof a corporate bond portfolio can be considered to be the objective function


Portfolio Optimization 185one wishes to m<strong>in</strong>imize. The set of constra<strong>in</strong>t functions can be formulatedon the expected return of the portfolio and the market risk exposures. Thesolution to this optimization problem then provides the portfolio managerwith an <strong>in</strong>dicative bond portfolio that can help <strong>in</strong> the portfolio constructionprocess. In the next section, I establish the set of constra<strong>in</strong>t functions <strong>in</strong>connection with the optimization problem for construct<strong>in</strong>g a replicat<strong>in</strong>gportfolio.Sett<strong>in</strong>g Up the Constra<strong>in</strong>tsI argued that <strong>in</strong> order to select implementable portfolios, one has to formulatethe optimization problem such that an efficient portfolio is selectedcompared to the benchmark. I also mentioned that for such an optimizationproblem the expected return of the portfolio and market risk exposuresserve as constra<strong>in</strong>t functions. To help formulate the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions ofthe optimization problem, denote the set of market risk factors modeled asN and the set of permissible bonds that can be held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio as N .The first set of constra<strong>in</strong>t functions is on the market risk factor exposuresof the portfolio. In Chapter 4, I def<strong>in</strong>ed six market risk factors and<strong>in</strong>dicated how the sensitivity to these risk factors at the portfolio level canbe determ<strong>in</strong>ed. To set up the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions for the optimal portfolioselection problem, however, one needs to know the sensitivity to variousmarket risk factors at the <strong>in</strong>dividual bond level. The sensitivity <strong>in</strong> basispo<strong>in</strong>ts of the ith bond to the kth market risk factor modeled can be determ<strong>in</strong>edfromf ik 10,000 Pk dirty,i P dirty,iP dirty,i(10.1)In equation (10.1), P dirty,i denotes the current dirty price of the bond for $1face value and P k dirty,i is the price after a shock to the kth market risk factor.If NE i denotes the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure to the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio,the market risk sensitivity to the kth risk factor is given by1M PaiHNNE i P dirty,i f ik(10.2)In equation (10.2), M P denotes the amount that needs to be <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> theportfolio. If the <strong>in</strong>tention is to have the same market risk sensitivity as thebenchmark portfolio to the kth risk factor, then this constra<strong>in</strong>t can beexpressed as follows:1M PaiHNNE i P dirty,i f ik S k B(10.3)


186 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSIn equation (10.3), SBk denotes the sensitivity of the benchmark to the kthmarket risk factor, which can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g equation (4.30) <strong>in</strong> Chapter4. In sett<strong>in</strong>g up the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions for the optimization problem,one can decide to enforce constra<strong>in</strong>ts on all or only some of the market riskfactors.The other constra<strong>in</strong>t is on the expected return of the bond portfolio.The expected return on a corporate bond portfolio is the effective yield ofthe portfolio less the percentage expected loss on the portfolio. In practice,it is more convenient to split this constra<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>to two separate constra<strong>in</strong>ts,one on the portfolio effective yield and the other on the percentage expectedloss of the portfolio. The effective yield of the portfolio is given byy P 1 M PaiHNNE i P dirty,i y i(10.4)If y B denotes the effective yield of the benchmark, the constra<strong>in</strong>t on theportfolio effective yield of the portfolio can be expressed as1M PaiHNNE i P dirty,i y i y B(10.5)The percentage expected loss on the portfolio is given by%EL P 1 M PaiHNNE i i(10.6)In equation (10.6), i corresponds to the expected loss on the ith bond held<strong>in</strong> the portfolio hav<strong>in</strong>g a nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure of $1. The percentage expectedloss given by equation (10.6) is evaluated either under the default mode orunder the migration mode depend<strong>in</strong>g on whether the optimization problemis formulated under the default mode or the migration mode, respectively.If the percentage expected loss of the benchmark is given by %EL B , then theconstra<strong>in</strong>t on expected loss can be expressed as1M PaiHNNE i i %EL B(10.7)The constra<strong>in</strong>t functions (10.5) and (10.7) jo<strong>in</strong>tly ensure that the expectedreturn of the portfolio is not lower than that of the benchmark.A standard requirement for any portfolio selection problem is that theportfolio is fully <strong>in</strong>vested. This requirement can be expressed <strong>in</strong> terms of thefollow<strong>in</strong>g constra<strong>in</strong>t:aiHN NE i P dirty,i M P(10.8)


Portfolio Optimization 187F<strong>in</strong>ally, to ensure that the portfolio does not have large exposures to a fewbonds, one needs to impose constra<strong>in</strong>ts on the maximum nom<strong>in</strong>al exposureto any bond issue. For <strong>in</strong>stance, one can impose this constra<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> terms ofthe maximum permissible nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfoliorelative to the issue size S i of the ith bond. If one chooses the exposurelimit to be 5 percent of the respective issue sizes for all bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio,this constra<strong>in</strong>t together with the constra<strong>in</strong>t of no short positions canbe expressed as0 NE i 0.05S i , i H N (10.9)In the next section, I formulate an optimization problem to aid the selectionof bonds <strong>in</strong> a portfolio construction process.The Optimization ProblemTo complete the formulation of the optimization problem, one needs to def<strong>in</strong>ethe objective function. I <strong>in</strong>dicated earlier that the objective function is the m<strong>in</strong>imizationof the credit risk of the portfolio. A useful measure of credit risk isthe unexpected loss of the corporate bond portfolio. If the square of the unexpectedloss of the portfolio is used as the objective function, then it is easy toshow that the optimization problem is a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem.Given the computational attractiveness of quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problems,I formulate the portfolio construction problem <strong>in</strong> this framework. The nextstep is to establish the objective function of the optimization problem.For notational simplicity, denote the unexpected loss of the ith bond fora nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure NE i asUL i NE i i(10.10)In equation (10.10), i denotes the unexpected loss of the ith bond held <strong>in</strong>the portfolio for a nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure of $1. Aga<strong>in</strong>, the unexpected loss ofthe bond can be computed either under the default mode or under themigration mode. If / ik denotes the loss correlation between the ith bondand kth bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio, the square of the percentage portfolio unexpectedloss is given by%UL 2 P 1 M 2 a a NE i NE k i k / ikP kHNiHN (10.11)It is important to mention that if the unexpected loss of the ith bond andthe loss correlation between the ith and the kth bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio aredeterm<strong>in</strong>ed under the migration mode, the portfolio unexpected loss will be


188 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOScaptured under the migration mode. The objective function of the optimizationproblem will be the m<strong>in</strong>imization of equation (10.11).At this stage, many will have recognized the design variable of theoptimization problem to be the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure amount of the ith bond<strong>in</strong> the portfolio. In general, some notational simplicity can be achieved ifthe design variables are transformed to be the relative nom<strong>in</strong>al weights ofthe bonds. The relative nom<strong>in</strong>al weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio isgiven byw i NE iM P(10.12)The optimization problem to solve to guide the portfolio constructionprocess is now as follows:M<strong>in</strong>imizea a w i w k i k / ikkHNiHN subject to the constra<strong>in</strong>tsa w i f ik P dirty,i S k B,iHN k H N aiHN w i y i P dirty,i y BaiHN w i i %EL Ba w i P dirty,i 1iHN 0 w i 0.05 S iM P,i H N It is aga<strong>in</strong> useful to emphasize that this optimization problem is a quadraticprogramm<strong>in</strong>g problem <strong>in</strong> the design variable w i , which represents the relativenom<strong>in</strong>al weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. The risk profile of theoptimal portfolio composition result<strong>in</strong>g from solv<strong>in</strong>g this quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>gproblem is presented <strong>in</strong> the next section.Optimal Portfolio CompositionAga<strong>in</strong> consider the 23-bond portfolio given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.6 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6 toserve as the benchmark portfolio. However, <strong>in</strong>stead of the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure


Portfolio Optimization 189to each bond be<strong>in</strong>g USD 20 million, assume that the nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure isUSD 200 million. Such a choice ensures that the benchmark risk profile isunaltered. I chose these nom<strong>in</strong>al exposures so that the benchmark compositionis representative of a typical market capitalization-based <strong>in</strong>dex. Inselect<strong>in</strong>g the optimal portfolio composition, assume that the amount to be<strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> the corporate bond portfolio is USD 73 million. The optimalportfolio compositions have been determ<strong>in</strong>ed both under the migrationmode (PMM) and the default mode (PDM) assum<strong>in</strong>g asset returns have amultivariate normal distribution. For comput<strong>in</strong>g the loss correlationbetween obligors, the asset return correlations given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 6.7 <strong>in</strong> Chapter6 were used. The composition of the optimal portfolios under the migrationand default modes is shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 10.1.In Exhibit 10.1, the optimal portfolio under the default mode was computedus<strong>in</strong>g KMV’s EDFs for the various issuers. Note that the compositionEXHIBIT 10.1Composition of Optimal <strong>Bond</strong> <strong>Portfolios</strong> aCoupon PMM PDM PSMS. No. Issuer Maturity (%) (mn $) (mn $) (mn $)1 Health Care Reit 15 Aug 07 7.500 1.721 10.000 1.2302 Hilton Hotels 15 May 08 7.625 1.374 2.367 1.3003 Apple Computer 15 Feb 04 6.500 1.998 1.039 1.5074 Delta Air L<strong>in</strong>es 15 Dec 09 7.900 1.179 2.949 0.9625 Alcoa Inc 01 Jun 06 5.875 2.150 1.661 1.6926 ABN Amro Bank 31 May 05 7.250 7.548 3.974 9.3737 Abbey Natl Plc 17 Nov 05 6.690 2.729 0.483 1.6518 Alliance Capital 15 Aug 06 5.625 7.187 0.000 9.2069 Aegon Nv 15 Aug 06 8.000 8.406 5.551 10.00010 Abbott Labs 01 Jul 06 5.625 0.038 5.401 0.12211 Caterpillar Inc 01 May 06 5.950 1.579 1.401 0.25312 Coca Cola Enter 15 Aug 06 5.375 0.957 0.206 0.00013 Countrywide Home 01 Aug 06 5.500 0.983 0.000 0.00014 Colgate-Palm Co 29 Apr 05 3.980 0.000 6.540 0.00015 Hershey Foods Co 01 Oct 05 6.700 2.074 10.000 2.20716 IBM Corp 01 Oct 06 4.875 0.235 1.412 0.00017 Johnson Controls 15 Nov 06 5.000 3.134 2.632 2.28618 JP Morgan Chase 01 Jun 05 7.000 5.280 0.490 4.98419 Bank One NA ILL 26 Mar 07 5.500 9.063 4.740 9.75620 Oracle Corp 15 Feb 07 6.910 7.225 1.460 8.76221 Pub Svc EL & Gas 01 Mar 06 6.750 3.709 0.520 4.09522 Procter & Gamble 30 Apr 05 4.000 0.000 6.382 0.00023 PNC Bank NA 01 Aug 06 5.750 0.997 1.289 0.000a PMM, Portfolio composition under migration mode; PDM, portfolio compositionunder default mode; PSM, portfolio composition under stress mode.


190 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 10.2 <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures for Portfolio Composition Under MigrationMode (PMM)PMM Portfolio Benchmark Active PortfolioDescription (bp) (bp) (bp)%EL 25.1 34.0 9.0%UL 72.6 88.8 46.8%CrVaR 90% 75.9 102.9 15.3%ESR 90% 174.8 240.3 38.9of the optimal portfolios under the migration and default modes is very different.This is to be expected because the default probabilities for the issuersare completely different if we adopt the KMV framework to estimate them.To provide a comparison of the various risk measures of the optimal portfolioaga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark, Exhibits 10.2 and 10.3 show the credit riskand market risk measures for the PMM portfolio.Remarks Compar<strong>in</strong>g the credit risk measures given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.5 <strong>in</strong>Chapter 9 and Exhibit 10.2, one can see that the optimal portfolio has asignificantly improved risk–return characteristic compared to the portfoliocomposition given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.1 <strong>in</strong> Chapter 9. The active portfolio,which serves to capture the relative risks, also has significantly lowerrisks when the PMM portfolio is used for benchmark replication. For<strong>in</strong>stance, the average underperformance <strong>in</strong> the worst-case 10 percent scenariosis reduced from 126 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts to 39 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts when the PMMportfolio is held. The market risk presented <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 10.3 shows thatboth the benchmark and the optimal portfolio have identical market riskexposures.At this stage, there might be some concern that hold<strong>in</strong>g any of theoptimal portfolios will require buy<strong>in</strong>g more than 90 percent of the bonds <strong>in</strong>EXHIBIT 10.3 Market <strong>Risk</strong> Measures for Portfolio Composition Under MigrationMode (PMM)Description Portfolio BenchmarkEffective yield (%) 5.58 5.58Effective duration 3.549 3.548Effective convexity 15.98 16.20%VaR (90% confidence level) (%) 3.41 3.41%ESR (90% confidence level) (%) 4.69 4.69Shift sensitivity (USD swap curve) (bp) 35.57 35.56Twist sensitivity (USD swap curve) (bp) 2.56 2.55


Portfolio Optimization 191the benchmark. For a benchmark compris<strong>in</strong>g several hundred bonds, sucha strategy will be very expensive from the transaction cost po<strong>in</strong>t of view. Inpractice, however, when the benchmark portfolio consists of several hundredbonds, an optimal replicat<strong>in</strong>g portfolio compris<strong>in</strong>g only a fraction ofthe bonds <strong>in</strong> the benchmark can be found.F<strong>in</strong>ally, it is important to observe that the optimal portfolio is not a truereplicat<strong>in</strong>g portfolio because there is still considerable residual credit riskbetween the benchmark and the optimal portfolio. However, this was notthe <strong>in</strong>tention <strong>in</strong> the first place, as can be seen from the formulation of theoptimal portfolio selection problem.Robustness of Portfolio CompositionThe optimal portfolio composition under the migration mode <strong>in</strong> Exhibit10.1 was determ<strong>in</strong>ed under normal market conditions. A question of practical<strong>in</strong>terest here is how the composition of the PMM portfolio changes ifsome <strong>in</strong>put parameters used <strong>in</strong> the credit model are changed. In otherwords, one is <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the robustness of the optimal portfolio compositionunder different model parameter assumptions. To exam<strong>in</strong>e this, thecredit risk model parameters were changed to <strong>in</strong>troduce a 20 percent stressfactor scenario discussed <strong>in</strong> Chapter 9. The optimal portfolio compositionfor this scenario was computed under the migration mode with the multivariatet-distribution assumption for asset returns. The composition of theoptimal portfolio result<strong>in</strong>g from this exercise is shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 10.1under the head<strong>in</strong>g PSM.Notice that <strong>in</strong> spite of the large changes to the model <strong>in</strong>put parameters,the portfolio composition reveals similar under- and over-weight positions<strong>in</strong> the bonds relative to the benchmark composition. Clearly, this suggeststhat the portfolio composition is less sensitive to parameter uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty,provided the model<strong>in</strong>g framework for credit risk measurement rema<strong>in</strong>s thesame. Based on this observation, it is fair to say that the optimal portfolioselection approach presented here will help a portfolio manager to identifya list of bonds and the relative nom<strong>in</strong>al amounts to be held <strong>in</strong> the portfolioconstruction process.PORTFOLIO REBALANCINGThe focus so far has been on how to construct a portfolio when a newportfolio mandate is awarded. However, this is someth<strong>in</strong>g that happensrather <strong>in</strong>frequently <strong>in</strong> the portfolio management bus<strong>in</strong>ess. A case of muchmore practical <strong>in</strong>terest to portfolio managers concerns the rebalanc<strong>in</strong>gtrades that need to be carried out result<strong>in</strong>g either from changes to the


192 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSbenchmark composition or from <strong>in</strong>jections and withdrawals from theportfolio that may take place periodically. An important requirementwhen rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g trades are performed is to keep the turnover of theportfolio small to m<strong>in</strong>imize the transactions costs. I def<strong>in</strong>e turnover as thepercentage of the current market value of the portfolio that needs to beliquidated to rebalance the portfolio (exclud<strong>in</strong>g the part required to meetcash withdrawals).Enforc<strong>in</strong>g turnover constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> portfolio optimization problems israther difficult. The approach I take to <strong>in</strong>corporate this constra<strong>in</strong>t is tosolve the portfolio-rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g problem <strong>in</strong> a two-step process. In the firststep, one identifies a list of tentative sell transactions from the exist<strong>in</strong>gportfolio hold<strong>in</strong>gs that meets the turnover constra<strong>in</strong>t while reduc<strong>in</strong>g therelative credit risk between the portfolio and the benchmark. In the secondstep, one determ<strong>in</strong>es the actual transactions required to be done tak<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>to consideration the sell recommendations. These transactions are chosensuch that the rebalanced portfolio has improved risk-adjusted returnrelative to the benchmark. Follow<strong>in</strong>g such a two-step process keeps thecomplexity of the portfolio-rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g problem manageable. The detailsregard<strong>in</strong>g this optimization approach are discussed <strong>in</strong> what follows.Identify<strong>in</strong>g Sell TransactionsIn this section, I discuss the formulation of the optimization problem toidentify the tentative list of sell transactions. A key requirement <strong>in</strong> do<strong>in</strong>gthis is to keep the portfolio turnover small. If the portfolio rebalanc<strong>in</strong>gtrades have to be done primarily to meet cash withdrawals, the objective islimited to identify<strong>in</strong>g only the sell transactions. Hence, the problem ofgreater practical <strong>in</strong>terest is portfolio rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g under the condition thatthe net <strong>in</strong>jection <strong>in</strong>to the portfolio is either zero or positive. I assume thatthis is the case <strong>in</strong> the optimization problem formulation.Before proceed<strong>in</strong>g to set up the optimization problem, I def<strong>in</strong>e the follow<strong>in</strong>gvariables, which will be used <strong>in</strong> formulat<strong>in</strong>g the optimization problem.All exposure amounts given are assumed to be <strong>in</strong> the base currency ofthe portfolio.NE i,P Nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the current portfolio.NE i,B Nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the benchmark.NE i,sell Nom<strong>in</strong>al amount of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio to be sold.NE i,A Nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the active portfolio afterthe bond sale.M P Market value of the current portfolio exclud<strong>in</strong>g new cash<strong>in</strong>jections.M B Market value of the benchmark.


Portfolio Optimization 193w i,Pw i,Bw iw i,A i / ikN Weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the current portfolio, given byNE i,P M P . Weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the benchmark, given by NE i,B M B . Weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio to be sold, given byNE i M P . Weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the active portfolio after the bondsale, given by NE i,A M P . Unexpected loss of the ith bond for $1 nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure. Loss correlation between the ith and the kth bond. Set of permissible bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. Maximum permissible turnover as a percentage of currentportfolio size.I mentioned that the sell transactions will be chosen so as to reduce therelative credit risk between the portfolio and the benchmark. The relativecredit risk between the portfolio and the benchmark can be def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> termsof the unexpected loss of the active portfolio. Hence, the objective function ofthe optimization problem that identifies the sell transactions will be some suitablefunction of the unexpected loss of the active portfolio. I now formulatesuch an objective function that will enable us to identify the sell transactions.Assume that a portion w i of the ith bond hold<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the portfolio hasbeen sold. Under this scenario, the weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the active portfolioafter the bond sale is given byw i,A w i,P w i w i,B ,i H N (10.13)Note that if <strong>in</strong>vestments are made <strong>in</strong> bonds that are not conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>the benchmark, then the benchmark weights for those bonds are zero <strong>in</strong>equation (10.13). The square of the percentage unexpected loss of the activeportfolio after the bond sales is given by%UL 2 A a a w i,A w k,A i k / ikiHN kHN(10.14)In matrix notation, this equation can be compactly written as%UL 2 A w T A w A(10.15)/Here, is a matrix with elements ik i k ik and w A denotes the vectorof bond weights <strong>in</strong> the active portfolio. To develop the objective function ofthe optimization problem, one needs to expand the right-hand side ofequation (10.15) <strong>in</strong>to its component parts. Mak<strong>in</strong>g use of equation (10.13)


194 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSgives the follow<strong>in</strong>g relation:w T A w A (w P w w B ) T (w P w w B ) w T w 2(w B w P ) T w w T P w P w T B w B(10.16)Not<strong>in</strong>g that the last two terms <strong>in</strong> equation (10.16) are constants, one canrewrite equation (10.15) aswhere%UL 2 A w T w 2c T w constantc T (w B w P ) T (10.17)(10.18)If the objective is to m<strong>in</strong>imize the unexpected loss of the active portfolio,equation (10.17) can serve as a suitable objective function for the optimizationproblem.The constra<strong>in</strong>ts for the optimization problem are to limit the turnover tobe less than and to exclude the possibility of short positions <strong>in</strong> any bonds. Theoptimization problem for identify<strong>in</strong>g the sell transactions dur<strong>in</strong>g the first stageof the rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g process with these constra<strong>in</strong>ts imposed is given as follows:M<strong>in</strong>imizew T w 2c T wsubject to the constra<strong>in</strong>tsa w i iHN 0 w i w i,P , i H N The optimization problem formulated here is a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>gproblem. Solv<strong>in</strong>g this quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem provides a list oftentative sell transactions. The nom<strong>in</strong>al amounts associated with these selltransactions are given byNE i,sell w i M P ,i H N (10.19)In the next section, I discuss the second stage of the optimization process thatwill help identify the actual transactions to be done to rebalance the portfolio.Identify<strong>in</strong>g the Rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g TradesThe first stage of the optimization problem made it possible to identify thetransactions that will reduce the relative risk between the portfolio and thebenchmark. For the second stage of the optimization problem, assume thatthe portfolio hold<strong>in</strong>gs have been modified to take <strong>in</strong>to account the sale


Portfolio Optimization 195recommendations. With this change <strong>in</strong> place, one identifies the actual rebalanc<strong>in</strong>gtrades to be performed such that the rebalanced portfolio replicatesthe market risk characteristics of the benchmark and offers an improvedrisk-adjusted return relative to the benchmark. The follow<strong>in</strong>g mathematicalformulation of the optimization problem assumes that all cash hold<strong>in</strong>gshave to be fully <strong>in</strong>vested.Let C I denote the cash <strong>in</strong>jection <strong>in</strong>to the portfolio. The new marketvalue of the portfolio after the cash <strong>in</strong>jection is given byM P M P C I(10.20)The new bond hold<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the portfolio assum<strong>in</strong>g the nom<strong>in</strong>al amountsgiven by equation (10.19) are sold is given byNE i,P NE i,P NE i,sell ,i H N (10.21)The relative weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio after the tentative bondsales is given byx i,P NE i,P M P ,i H N (10.22)If NE i,buy denotes the nom<strong>in</strong>al amount of the ith bond that is bought, therelative weight of this bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio is given byx i NE i,buy M P(10.23)After execut<strong>in</strong>g these transactions, the relative weight of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> theportfolio is x i x i,P . The square of the percentage unexpected loss of theportfolio with these bond hold<strong>in</strong>gs is given by%UL 2 P a a (x i x i,P )(x k x k,P ) i k / ikiHN kHNIn matrix notation, this equation can be compactly written as(10.24)%UL 2 P (x x P ) T (x x P ) x T x 2x T P x x T P x P(10.25)Consider<strong>in</strong>g that the relative weight vector x P(10.25) can be rewritten asis a constant, equation%UL 2 P x T x 2b T x constant(10.26)I mentioned that the buy transaction will be driven by the motivation toimprove the risk-adjusted return of the portfolio relative to the benchmark.


196 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSIn this case, equation (10.26) can serve as a suitable objective function to theoptimization problem. It is useful to note that the design variables for theoptimization problem are the relative weights x i of the ith bond to be bought.The constra<strong>in</strong>t functions for the optimization problem are very similarto the ones imposed for the portfolio construction process. The only differenceis that the design variables here are the relative weights of the <strong>in</strong>crementalbuy transactions, whereas earlier they were the relative weights ofthe bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. Tak<strong>in</strong>g account of this difference <strong>in</strong> the constra<strong>in</strong>tfunction formulations, the optimization problem to determ<strong>in</strong>e thebuy transactions can be stated as follows:M<strong>in</strong>imizex T x 2b T xsubject to the constra<strong>in</strong>tsa x i f ik P dirty,i SB k a x i,P f ik P dirty,i ,iHN iHNk H N a x i y i P dirty,i y B a x i,P y i P dirty,i toleranceiHN iHNa x i i %EL B a x i,P iiHN iHNa x i P dirty, i 1 a x i,P P dirty, iiHN iHN0 x i 0.05 S iM P x i,P ,i H N Note that the constra<strong>in</strong>t function for the portfolio yield <strong>in</strong>troduces a smalltolerance for deviation below the benchmark’s yield. Introduc<strong>in</strong>g this toleranceprovides some flexibility <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g suitable rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g trades whilemeet<strong>in</strong>g the turnover constra<strong>in</strong>t. I chose a 5-basis po<strong>in</strong>t tolerance for yielddeviation <strong>in</strong> the numerical examples presented <strong>in</strong> the next section.Remarks Practitioners may f<strong>in</strong>d the constra<strong>in</strong>t function on the market riskfactors k H N rather restrictive. In this case, some of the market risk factorscan be relaxed or some tolerances could be set. One could also consider collaps<strong>in</strong>gall the market risk factor constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong>to a s<strong>in</strong>gle constra<strong>in</strong>t on theeffective duration of the portfolio. For <strong>in</strong>stance, if D B denotes the effectiveduration of the benchmark and D i the effective duration of the ith bond <strong>in</strong>the portfolio, the market risk constra<strong>in</strong>t can be expressed simply asa x i D i D B a x i,P D iiHN iHN


Portfolio Optimization 197If corporate bonds denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> currencies other than the base currencyof the portfolio are held, the result<strong>in</strong>g exchange rate risk can be hedgedthrough currency forwards separately. Note that if only the effective durationof the portfolio is set to be equal to that of the benchmark, there willbe a small residual track<strong>in</strong>g error aris<strong>in</strong>g from market risk factors.Numerical ResultsAssume that the current portfolio hold<strong>in</strong>g is the one given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 9.1 <strong>in</strong>Chapter 9 and the benchmark is the 23-bond portfolio with nom<strong>in</strong>al exposuresof USD 200 million each. Consider rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g this portfolio with a10 percent turnover constra<strong>in</strong>t. The two-step optimization processdescribed here has been used to identify the rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g trades. Exhibit 10.4EXHIBIT 10.4Composition of Rebalanced <strong>Bond</strong> <strong>Portfolios</strong> aCPH RMM RDM RSMS. No. Issuer Maturity (mn $) (mn $) (mn $) (mn $)1 Health Care Reit 15 Aug 07 10.000 4.791 10.000 5.6132 Hilton Hotels 15 May 08 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.0003 Apple Computer 15 Feb 04 0.000 1.497 1.018 1.6554 Delta Air L<strong>in</strong>es 15 Dec 09 0.000 3.289 2.817 3.0735 Alcoa Inc 01 Jun 06 10.000 10.000 10.000 10.0006 ABN Amro Bank 31 May 05 0.000 0.000 1.089 0.0007 Abbey Natl Plc 17 Nov 05 10.000 10.000 10.000 10.0008 Alliance Capital 15 Aug 06 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.0009 Aegon Nv 15 Aug 06 0.000 0.000 1.319 0.00010 Abbott Labs 01 Jul 06 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00011 Caterpillar Inc 01 May 06 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00012 Coca Cola Enter 15 Aug 06 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00013 Countrywide Home 01 Aug 06 10.000 10.000 5.348 10.00014 Colgate-Palm Co 29 Apr 05 10.000 10.000 10.000 10.00015 Hershey Foods Co 01 Oct 05 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00016 IBM Corp 01 Oct 06 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00017 Johnson Controls 15 Nov 06 0.000 0.000 0.056 0.00018 JP Morgan Chase 01 Jun 05 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00019 Bank One NA ILL 26 Mar 07 0.000 2.925 1.297 3.02120 Oracle Corp 15 Feb 07 10.000 8.854 7.606 8.70021 Pub Svc EL & Gas 01 Mar 06 10.000 9.055 9.746 8.38622 Procter & Gamble 30 Apr 05 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.00023 PNC Bank NA 01 Aug 06 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000a CPH, Current portfolio hold<strong>in</strong>g; RMM, rebalanced portfolio under migration mode;RDM, rebalanced portfolio under default mode; RSM, rebalanced portfolio understress mode.


198 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 10.5 <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures for Rebalanced Portfolio Under MigrationMode (RMM)RMM Portfolio Benchmark Active PortfolioDescription (bp) (bp) (bp)%EL 33.6 34.0 0.4%UL 101.9 88.8 63.4%CrVaR 90% 105.6 102.9 26.3%ESR 90% 251.0 240.3 76.3shows the composition of the rebalanced portfolios when different creditrisk aggregation methods are used. Also shown <strong>in</strong> this exhibit is the rebalancedportfolio under a 20 percent stress factor scenario and multivariate tdistribution for asset returns.Note that although the composition of the rebalanced portfolios underthe migration mode and the stress mode are very similar, the portfolio compositionunder the default mode is somewhat different.Exhibit 10.5 provides a comparison of various credit risk measures of<strong>in</strong>terest for the portfolio and the benchmark. Compar<strong>in</strong>g Exhibit 9.5 <strong>in</strong>Chapter 9 and Exhibit 10.5 shows that the credit risk measures of the portfolioare more aligned with the benchmark’s credit risk measures after therebalanc<strong>in</strong>g. One can also <strong>in</strong>fer this from the relative risk measures capturedby the active portfolio. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the ESR at 90 percent level ofconfidence for the rebalanced portfolio is roughly 50 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts lowerthan for the orig<strong>in</strong>al portfolio composition. The market risk measures given<strong>in</strong> Exhibit 10.6 <strong>in</strong>dicate that there is very little relative market risk betweenthe portfolio and the benchmark.EXHIBIT 10.6 Market <strong>Risk</strong> Measures for Rebalanced Portfolio UnderMigration ModeDescription Portfolio BenchmarkEffective yield (%) 5.55 5.58Effective duration 3.549 3.548Effective convexity 16.05 16.20%VaR (90% confidence level) (%) 3.41 3.41%ESR (90% confidence level) (%) 4.69 4.69Shift sensitivity (USD swap curve) (bp) 35.57 35.56Twist sensitivity (USD swap curve) (bp) 2.56 2.55


Portfolio Optimization 199DEVIL IN THE PARAMETERS: A CASE STUDYPractitioners view the use of optimization techniques for portfolio selectionwith skepticism. A major criticism of optimization techniques is that thecomposition of the optimal portfolio is very sensitive to the choice of the<strong>in</strong>put parameters. Because the errors <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>put parameter estimates can belarge, the practical value of the optimal portfolio composition is often put toquestion. Much of this criticism has been directed aga<strong>in</strong>st mean-varianceportfolio optimization for which the estimate of the expected return ofassets <strong>in</strong> the portfolio plays an important role <strong>in</strong> the composition of theoptimal portfolio. It is natural that practitioners will have similar concernsas regards the portfolio composition derived us<strong>in</strong>g optimization techniquesfor replicat<strong>in</strong>g a corporate bond benchmark. In particular, practitionerswould wish to know how the composition of the optimal portfolio changesfor a different parametrization of the credit risk model as applied to a realworldportfolio construction problem.To address this, I consider the bond portfolio selection problem presented<strong>in</strong> Ramaswamy (2002) for replicat<strong>in</strong>g a s<strong>in</strong>gle-A rated corporate benchmark<strong>in</strong> the 1- to 5-year sector of the U.S. dollar market. 1 This benchmark,constructed as of 31 August 2001, conta<strong>in</strong>s 655 bonds. Contrast<strong>in</strong>g the optimalportfolio composition presented <strong>in</strong> that study with the optimal portfoliocomposition result<strong>in</strong>g from the use of the model<strong>in</strong>g parametrization suggested<strong>in</strong> this book will provide an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g case study for practitioners. Thisis because both approaches are similar <strong>in</strong> terms of formulat<strong>in</strong>g the portfolioselection problem. However, the model parameters for comput<strong>in</strong>g credit riskused <strong>in</strong> the study are quite different from the ones used here. The importantdifferences are that the recovery rate and its volatility are estimated for each<strong>in</strong>dustry sector and correlation between <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong>dex returns is used to <strong>in</strong>ferthe asset return correlation between obligors. Furthermore, for comput<strong>in</strong>gportfolio credit risk, loss given default values <strong>in</strong>stead of loss on default anddefault correlation rather than loss correlation are used.The question of <strong>in</strong>terest is how the composition of the optimal portfoliowill differ from the one reported <strong>in</strong> Ramaswamy (2002) when theparametrization suggested <strong>in</strong> this book for model<strong>in</strong>g credit is used. A moreimportant question, however, is whether it is possible to expla<strong>in</strong> the differences<strong>in</strong> the portfolio composition on the basis of the model parameters usedto quantify credit risk. If it is possible to relate the differences <strong>in</strong> portfoliocomposition to particular model parameter choices, then it will be possibleto make value judgments as to how one can deviate from the optimal portfoliocomposition if it is deemed necessary from an implementation perspective.To address the last po<strong>in</strong>t, I briefly review the important differences<strong>in</strong> the choice of the credit risk model parameters.


200 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSThe most obvious difference <strong>in</strong> model parameter values is the recoveryrate statistic used to quantify credit risk at the obligor level. Whereas theapproach taken <strong>in</strong> this book does not dist<strong>in</strong>guish between recovery rate statisticsfor senior unsecured bonds at the obligor level, the approach taken<strong>in</strong> Ramaswamy (2002) makes this dist<strong>in</strong>ction explicit, the details of whichare shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 10.7. The recovery rate statistics shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit10.7 are based on a study reported by Altman and Kishore, which documentsthe observed variations <strong>in</strong> recovery rates across <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors us<strong>in</strong>gdefaulted bond data over the period 1971 to 1995. 2The second important difference is the choice of the asset return correlationvalues between obligor pairs <strong>in</strong> the Ramaswamy study. Motivated bythe approach taken <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Credit</strong>Metrics Technical Document, correlationsbetween different <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong>dex returns are used as a proxy for <strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>gasset return correlation between obligor pairs. Specifically, obligors aremapped to different <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors (38 <strong>in</strong> all) and the equity <strong>in</strong>dustry<strong>in</strong>dex return correlations are scaled by a factor of 0.4 to proxy asset returncorrelations between obligors.To make the comparisons mean<strong>in</strong>gful, I adopt the default modeapproach to construct the optimal portfolio. Furthermore, I use the 1-yearEDFs provided by KMV Corporation as of end of July 2001 as an estimateof the default probabilities for obligors <strong>in</strong> the benchmark as <strong>in</strong> theRamaswamy study. The composition of the optimal portfolios and thebenchmark broken down at the <strong>in</strong>dustry sector level are shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit10.8. In this exhibit, the column under Study corresponds to the optimalportfolio composition reported <strong>in</strong> the Ramaswamy study and the columnunder Book corresponds to the optimal portfolio composition when themodel parameters suggested <strong>in</strong> this book are used.Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Exhibit 10.8 shows some significant differences <strong>in</strong> exposuresto various <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors when different model parametrizations areused. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the Book composition has almost benchmark-neutralexposure to banks but has a significant overweight relative to the Studycomposition. Both portfolios overweight the utilities sector relative to thebenchmark, but the Study composition has a significantly greater exposureto utilities. A careful exam<strong>in</strong>ation of the recovery rate statistics for thesetwo <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors reveals that the assumed recovery rate for the bank<strong>in</strong>gsector is 29.3 percent and that for the utilities sector is 70.5 percent,both be<strong>in</strong>g widely different from the <strong>in</strong>dustrywide average recovery rate of47 percent. 3 This leads to a large overweight of the utilities sector and asignificant underweight of the bank<strong>in</strong>g sector <strong>in</strong> the optimal portfolio compositionunder Study.Besides the actual recovery rate values, the volatility of the recoveryrate values also appears to have a marg<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>fluence on the portfolio composition.For <strong>in</strong>stance, the textiles and apparel sector has very low recovery


Portfolio Optimization 201EXHIBIT 10.7Recovery Rate Statistics for Various IndustriesRecovery LGD Vol LGDMSCI Industry a Code (%) (%) (%)Aerospace and military technology AERO 38.4 61.6 28.0Construction and hous<strong>in</strong>g CONS 35.3 64.7 28.7Data process<strong>in</strong>g and reproduction DP 37.1 62.9 20.8Electrical and electronics EL 46.1 53.9 20.1Electronic components, <strong>in</strong>struments ECOM 46.1 53.9 20.1Energy equipment and services ENEQ 47.4 52.6 20.1Industrial components INDC 47.4 52.6 25.0Mach<strong>in</strong>ery and eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g MACH 50.5 49.5 25.0Appliances and household durables APP 40.1 59.9 25.0Automobiles AUTO 42.3 57.7 25.0Beverages and tobacco BEV 45.3 54.7 21.7Food and household products FOOD 45.3 54.7 21.7Health and personal care HLTH 26.5 73.5 22.7Recreation and others REC 40.2 59.8 25.7Textiles and apparel TEX 31.7 68.3 15.2Energy sources EN 67.3 32.7 18.0Utilities, electrical and gas UT 70.5 29.5 19.5Bank<strong>in</strong>g BANK 29.3 70.7 25.7F<strong>in</strong>ancial services FIN 42.1 57.9 25.7Insurance INS 31.5 68.5 25.7Real estate RE 34.2 65.8 28.7Multi-<strong>in</strong>dustry MULT 48.7 51.3 25.0Gold m<strong>in</strong>es GOLD 40.7 59.3 18.0Build<strong>in</strong>g materials and components BM 32.3 67.7 22.9Chemicals CHEM 58.0 42.0 27.1Forest products and paper FP 29.8 70.2 24.4Metals, nonferrous MNF 46.1 53.9 22.9Metals, steel STL 46.1 53.9 22.9Miscellaneous materials and commodities MMC 32.2 67.8 22.9Broadcast<strong>in</strong>g and publish<strong>in</strong>g BRD 39.0 61.0 20.8Bus<strong>in</strong>ess and public services BS 46.2 53.8 25.0Leisure and tourism LEI 40.2 59.8 25.7Merchandis<strong>in</strong>g MER 33.2 66.8 20.5Telecommunications TEL 26.4 73.6 20.8Transportation, airl<strong>in</strong>es AIR 39.5 60.5 28.0Transportation, road and rail RR 43.6 56.4 28.0Transportation, shipp<strong>in</strong>g SHIP 38.4 61.6 28.0Wholesale and <strong>in</strong>ternational trade TRD 44.0 56.0 22.1a Morgan Stanley Capital International.


202 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 10.8Sector Concentrations of Benchmark and Optimal <strong>Portfolios</strong>Benchmark Study Book MModeMSCI Industry a (%) (%) (%) (%)Aerospace and military technology 1.19 4.72 2.23 2.56Construction and hous<strong>in</strong>g 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0Data process<strong>in</strong>g and reproduction 0.71 0.0 3.30 4.06Electrical and electronics 0.27 0.0 0.44 0.88Electronic components, <strong>in</strong>struments 1.53 0.0 2.94 3.71Energy equipment and services 1.94 4.79 3.27 6.04Industrial components 0.14 1.26 1.85 0.39Mach<strong>in</strong>ery and eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g 1.51 1.80 2.37 5.38Appliances and household durables 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0Automobiles 14.68 0.0 0.75 2.31Beverages and tobacco 2.78 7.21 7.05 6.41Food and household products 2.23 7.56 9.66 8.83Health and personal care 1.67 4.16 3.73 4.62Recreation and others 0.52 0.0 0.0 1.45Textiles and apparel 0.26 2.58 1.45 0.97Energy sources 0.36 2.99 0.0 0.20Utilities, electrical and gas 3.62 14.17 8.34 16.01Bank<strong>in</strong>g 19.73 9.64 20.03 8.09F<strong>in</strong>ancial services 27.15 8.72 6.69 3.30Insurance 3.31 7.37 4.95 3.55Real estate 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0Multi-<strong>in</strong>dustry 2.09 4.88 0.90 1.26Gold m<strong>in</strong>es 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0Build<strong>in</strong>g materials and components 0.25 2.47 2.66 1.52Chemicals 0.59 3.92 1.56 0.36Forest products and paper 0.40 1.00 0.78 0.26Metals, nonferrous 0.68 5.04 1.07 1.87Metals, steel 0.09 0.0 0.11 0.93Miscellaneous materials and commodities 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0Broadcast<strong>in</strong>g and publish<strong>in</strong>g 2.84 1.26 5.20 3.43Bus<strong>in</strong>ess and public services 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0Leisure and tourism 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0Merchandis<strong>in</strong>g 1.28 1.00 4.93 3.96Telecommunications 7.36 0.0 3.16 6.34Transportation, airl<strong>in</strong>es 0.14 1.12 0.0 0.11Transportation, road and rail 0.51 2.35 0.01 0.96Transportation, shipp<strong>in</strong>g 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0Wholesale and <strong>in</strong>ternational trade 0.20 0.0 0.57 0.20a Morgan Stanley Capital International.


Portfolio Optimization 203rate volatility as reported <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 10.7. Although its recovery value of31.7 percent is lower than the <strong>in</strong>dustrywide average, the volatility of recoveryrates is 15.2 percent, which is well below the <strong>in</strong>dustrywide average of 25percent. Because a lower value of recovery rate volatility reduces the unexpectedloss at the obligor level, such <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors tend to have greaterweights <strong>in</strong> Study. However, the effect of recovery rate volatility on the optimalportfolio composition is not very significant.The other parameter that can <strong>in</strong>fluence the optimal portfolio compositionis the asset return correlation between obligors. To test the sensitivityof the portfolio composition to changes <strong>in</strong> asset return correlation, assetreturn correlations were <strong>in</strong>creased by 20 percent and the portfolio constructionproblem re-solved. It was observed, however, that this change hadno significant <strong>in</strong>fluence on the relative portfolio allocations to different<strong>in</strong>dustry sectors. When us<strong>in</strong>g an optimization approach to select a corporatebond portfolio, the recovery rates for different <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors, if chosento be different, need to be carefully selected because they have a strong<strong>in</strong>fluence on the relative weights among various <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors.To complete the analysis of the effects of alternate model parametrizationson the composition of the optimal portfolio, consider the case of portfolioconstruction under the migration mode. In this case, the issuer’sdefault probability and rat<strong>in</strong>g transit<strong>in</strong>g probabilities are determ<strong>in</strong>ed by therat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix, and these <strong>in</strong> turn are a function of the current creditrat<strong>in</strong>g of the issuer. The credit risk model parameters used for portfolioconstruction under the migration mode are identical to those used for comput<strong>in</strong>gthe portfolio composition of Book except for the use of the rat<strong>in</strong>gmigration matrix to def<strong>in</strong>e the default and transition probabilities. In particular,the recovery rate statistics were not differentiated among issuers,and the average recovery rate was set to 47 percent and the volatility of therecovery rate was set to 25 percent. The composition of the optimal portfoliounder the migration mode is also shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 10.8 under thehead<strong>in</strong>g MMode. The important difference between this portfolio compositionand the composition of the Book portfolio is that there is a significantoverweight assigned to the utilities sector and the allocation to bank<strong>in</strong>g sectoris small relative to the benchmark weight.<strong>Risk</strong> ReductionThe discussions so far focused on exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the differences <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry sectorconcentrations of the optimal portfolios. From a portfolio manager’sperspective, it is also important to know the level of risk reduction relativeto the benchmark and the number of bonds required to replicate the benchmark.Because the parameters used to quantify credit risk are different foreach of the optimal portfolios, the most mean<strong>in</strong>gful way to measure the


204 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 10.9<strong>Risk</strong> Diversification RatiosOptimal Portfolio EL Ratio UL Ratio No. of <strong>Bond</strong>sStudy 0.379 0.391 75Book 0.344 0.366 120MMode 0.855 0.644 142reduction <strong>in</strong> credit risk for the optimal portfolios is to exam<strong>in</strong>e the expectedand unexpected loss ratios relative to the benchmark. Specifically, theexpected loss ratio is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the ratio between the expected loss of theportfolio and the expected loss of the benchmark, where both losses arecomputed us<strong>in</strong>g the same model parametrization. The unexpected loss ratiois similarly def<strong>in</strong>ed. Exhibit 10.9 shows the loss ratios for the three optimalportfolios considered here.It is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to note that both Study and Book portfolios achievesimilar levels of risk reduction relative to the benchmark. For <strong>in</strong>stance, theoptimal portfolio denoted Book has an expected loss ratio of 0.344. Thiscorresponds to a risk reduction of the expected loss by 65.6 percent relativeto the benchmark. The risk reduction of the unexpected loss of this portfoliorelative to the benchmark is 63.4 percent. In terms of the number ofbonds required to construct the optimal portfolio, the Book portfoliorequires considerably more, but it is still less than 20 percent of the bonds<strong>in</strong> the benchmark. An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g observation is that the risk reduction forthe MMode portfolio is substantially less relative to what is achieved whenthe default mode is used for quantify<strong>in</strong>g credit risk. The reason for this isthat when the rat<strong>in</strong>g transition matrix is used, the relative differences <strong>in</strong>default probabilities between s<strong>in</strong>gle-A rated obligors are significantly lowerthan <strong>in</strong> the case when EDF values are used to determ<strong>in</strong>e default probabilities.As a result, the possible risk reduction is also correspond<strong>in</strong>gly limited.Note also that the number of bonds required for benchmark replication isconsiderably more for the MMode portfolio.QUESTIONS1. With reference to a corporate bond portfolio, what are the benefits oftak<strong>in</strong>g a quantitative approach to portfolio selection?2. What is the difference between a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem anda nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problem? Why is it computationally moredifficult to solve a nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problem?3. A portfolio selection problem is posed as the m<strong>in</strong>imization of the track<strong>in</strong>gerror of the portfolio subject to the constra<strong>in</strong>t that the portfolio


Portfolio Optimization 205duration and benchmark duration are identical. What type of a programm<strong>in</strong>gproblem is this?4. What are the practical difficulties that can arise when a quantitativeapproach is used to either construct or rebalance corporate bond portfolios?5. The portfolio construction problem was posed as a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>gproblem. Is it possible to formulate the optimal portfolioconstruction problem as a l<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problem? Justify youranswer.6. What are the practical difficulties <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g rebalanc<strong>in</strong>gtrades us<strong>in</strong>g the portfolio construction problem formulation?7. Briefly expla<strong>in</strong> the motivation for solv<strong>in</strong>g the portfolio-rebalanc<strong>in</strong>gproblem us<strong>in</strong>g a two-step process.8. Consider the case where the objective function of the portfoliorebalanc<strong>in</strong>gproblem is chosen to m<strong>in</strong>imize the turnover of the portfolio.What type of an optimization problem is this?9. The devil-<strong>in</strong>-the-parameters case study showed that the composition ofthe optimal portfolios is <strong>in</strong>fluenced by the choice of the credit risk modelparameters. Which model parameters require careful estimation?


CHAPTER 11Structured <strong>Credit</strong> ProductsSo far <strong>in</strong> this book, I have analyzed how credit risk <strong>in</strong> a corporate bondportfolio can be quantified and how the relative risk of the portfolioaga<strong>in</strong>st a benchmark can be measured and managed. The risk quantificationtechniques presented <strong>in</strong> the earlier chapters can be used to analyze thecredit risk <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> structured credit products whose collateral poolcomprises corporate bonds. Examples of such structured credit products<strong>in</strong>clude Morgan Stanley’s Tradable Custodial Receipts (Tracers) and LehmanBrothers Targeted Return Index Securities (Tra<strong>in</strong>s). Tracers and Tra<strong>in</strong>s provide<strong>in</strong>vestors with the opportunity to trade a portfolio of corporate bondsthrough one trade execution.Other popular structured credit products that are backed by a collateralpool of securities or bank loans come under the broad category of collateralizeddebt obligations (CDOs). The cash flows generated through<strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong>come and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal repayments from the collateral pool are allocatedto a prioritized collection of CDO securities referred to as tranches.The standard prioritization scheme used is simple subord<strong>in</strong>ation: SeniorCDO notes are paid before mezzan<strong>in</strong>e and lower subord<strong>in</strong>ated notes, andany residual cash is paid to an equity tranche. A CDO structure can hold <strong>in</strong>its collateral pool of assets corporate bonds, bank loans, emerg<strong>in</strong>g marketdebt, or asset-backed securities. A CDO structure can also ga<strong>in</strong> exposure tothese assets synthetically. The annual CDO issuance has grown from roughly$4 billion prior to 1996 to above $120 billion <strong>in</strong> 2000.This chapter provides a brief <strong>in</strong>troduction to the structured credit productsCDOs and Tracers. In the first part of this chapter, I focus on CDOsand expla<strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> features of this product. I then discuss how rat<strong>in</strong>gagencies evaluate the credit risk <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> CDOs and assign rat<strong>in</strong>gs to differenttranches of the CDO. In the second part of this chapter, I give a brief<strong>in</strong>troduction to tradable corporate bond baskets and expla<strong>in</strong> why this andsimilar products are attractive from an <strong>in</strong>vestor’s perspective. I then focuson the structured credit product Tracers and expla<strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> features ofthis product. This is followed by an outl<strong>in</strong>e of a procedure to evaluate therisks <strong>in</strong> Tracers us<strong>in</strong>g the credit risk quantification approach presented <strong>in</strong>206


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 207the earlier chapters of this book. By deriv<strong>in</strong>g an implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of thisstructured credit product us<strong>in</strong>g a tail risk measure, I highlight the differences<strong>in</strong> credit rat<strong>in</strong>g that can result from us<strong>in</strong>g the approach presented hereas opposed to the rat<strong>in</strong>g agency approaches.INTRODUCTION TO CDOsA CDO is a structured credit product that can be broadly categorized <strong>in</strong>totwo dist<strong>in</strong>ct groups: balance sheet CDOs and arbitrage CDOs. Balance sheetCDOs are packaged by transferr<strong>in</strong>g the loans or assets from the balance sheetand hence have an impact on the balance sheet of the orig<strong>in</strong>ator. ArbitrageCDOs, on the other hand, are packaged by buy<strong>in</strong>g bonds or other assets <strong>in</strong>the market, pool<strong>in</strong>g them together, and then securtitiz<strong>in</strong>g the assets. Theprime objective <strong>in</strong> balance sheet CDOs is the reduction of regulatory capital,whereas for arbitrage CDOs the objective is to make arbitrage profits. A furthersubclassification of CDOs is possible depend<strong>in</strong>g on whether the collateralcan be traded or not. In the former case, the CDO is referred to as a cashflow CDO, and <strong>in</strong> the latter case, as a market value CDO. Besides these classifications,it is possible to group CDOs <strong>in</strong>to cash and synthetic CDOs. CashCDOs are those that <strong>in</strong>vest directly <strong>in</strong> bonds, loans, or other securities thatconstitute the collateral pool, whereas synthetic CDOs ga<strong>in</strong> exposure to thecollateral pool through credit default swaps or total return swaps.As an asset class, CDOs are grouped under the asset-backed securitiesmarket because of the similarities <strong>in</strong> the fundamental structures that governboth asset classes. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a CDO is a debt obligation issued by abankruptcy-remote special-purpose vehicle (SPV) secured by some form ofreceivable. The receivables are the <strong>in</strong>terest and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments from thesecuritized assets held <strong>in</strong> the bankruptcy-remote SPV. CDO securities typicallyconsist of credit tranches rang<strong>in</strong>g from triple A to s<strong>in</strong>gle B or unrated,a feature common to asset-backed securities (ABS). Furthermore, the rat<strong>in</strong>gof each CDO tranche is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by credit enhancement, ongo<strong>in</strong>g collateralcredit performance, and the <strong>in</strong>terest payment priority from the cashflows generated from the collateral pool. In all these respects, a CDO transactionis fundamentally similar to an ABS transaction.In this section, I briefly exam<strong>in</strong>e the major differences among varioustypes of CDOs and discuss the motivation for CDO issuance. I also <strong>in</strong>dicatewhat characteristics make CDOs appeal<strong>in</strong>g to a wide <strong>in</strong>vestor base.Balance Sheet versus Arbitrage CDOsCDOs can be classified as either balance sheet or arbitrage CDOs depend<strong>in</strong>gon the motivation beh<strong>in</strong>d the securitization and the source of the assets.


208 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSBalance sheet CDOs are <strong>in</strong>itiated by holders of securitizable assets, such ascommercial banks, that desire to sell part of their risky assets to <strong>in</strong>vestors.The ma<strong>in</strong> motivation for issu<strong>in</strong>g balance sheet CDOs is to either reduce theregulatory capital requirement or reduce risk concentrations to certa<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>dustry sectors aris<strong>in</strong>g from the bank lend<strong>in</strong>g activities. Balance sheetCDOs can be <strong>in</strong>itiated through a cash sale of the assets <strong>in</strong>to a SPV, whichare then securitized <strong>in</strong>to different CDO credit tranches and sold to<strong>in</strong>vestors. If the assets that constitute the collateral pool are made up ofbank loans, the CDO transaction is referred to as a collateralized loan obligation(CLO). The bank orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the CLO usually reta<strong>in</strong>s the first-losspiece, or equivalently, the equity tranche. The sale of the loans <strong>in</strong>to the SPVwill free up regulatory capital charge, and the bank orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the CLOcan use the regulatory capital freed to fund other bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities.To illustrate how a CLO transaction helps free up capital for a bank,consider a bank that has a loan book of $1 billion, which consumes 8 percentcapital charge, that is, $80 million. By do<strong>in</strong>g a CLO transaction, thebank can sell 98 percent of its loan book to <strong>in</strong>vestors and reta<strong>in</strong> an equitypiece worth 2 percent of the $1 billion. This equity piece will <strong>in</strong>cur a 100percent capital charge, which is equal to $20 million. By do<strong>in</strong>g this CLOtransaction, the bank has reduced its regulatory capital charge by $60 millionand this freed-up capital can be used to fund other prospective or highmarg<strong>in</strong>bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities. CLO transactions orig<strong>in</strong>ated by a bank to free upregulatory capital are usually large and consist mostly of <strong>in</strong>vestment-gradecommercial and <strong>in</strong>dustrial loans hav<strong>in</strong>g short maturities. These loans usuallyrepresent revolv<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>es of credit and the members of the pool areanonymous. To help analyze the <strong>in</strong>vestment risks, <strong>in</strong>vestors are suppliedwith statistical <strong>in</strong>formation on the distribution of the credit quality of theloans and the prepayment risks <strong>in</strong> the pool.In an arbitrage CDO, the sponsor raises funds <strong>in</strong> the capital marketsthrough the issuance of CDO securities to f<strong>in</strong>ance the purchase of a portfolioof assets <strong>in</strong> the open market. Typically, the sponsor will beg<strong>in</strong> to accumulatethe assets dur<strong>in</strong>g a warehous<strong>in</strong>g period prior to the CDO issuanceand complete the acquisition of the assets dur<strong>in</strong>g a 60- to 90-day ramp-upperiod after the CDO closes. The aim of arbitrage CDOs is to capture thearbitrage opportunity that exists <strong>in</strong> the credit spread differential betweenthe high-yield securities that constitute the collateral and the low-yield liabilitiesrepresented by the rated CDO notes.Sponsors of arbitrage CDOs <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>surance companies, <strong>in</strong>vestmentbanks, and asset managers. The sponsor of the arbitrage CDO often <strong>in</strong>vests<strong>in</strong> a portion of the equity tranche, which represents a leveraged <strong>in</strong>vestment<strong>in</strong> the underly<strong>in</strong>g collateral. Seen from the asset manager’s perspective, arbitrageCDOs create a high-return asset by reta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g part of the equitytranche and <strong>in</strong> addition create stable fee <strong>in</strong>come by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g assets under


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 209management. A typical arbitrage CDO conta<strong>in</strong>s 30 to 50 securities, whichcan <strong>in</strong>clude both loans and bonds. When the underly<strong>in</strong>g securities <strong>in</strong> thecollateral pool comprises only bonds, it is customary to refer to the CDOas a collateralized bond obligation (CBO). The credit of the collateral pool<strong>in</strong> arbitrage CDOs tends to be of lower quality than a balance sheet CDO,and is typically of BB to B rat<strong>in</strong>g. Transaction sizes also tend to be smaller,typically $200 million to $1 billion compared to $1 billion to $5 billion forbalance sheet CDOs.Cash Flow versus Market Value CDOsDepend<strong>in</strong>g on whether the collateral pool can be actively traded or not,CDOs can be further classified <strong>in</strong>to cash flow and market value CDOs. Ina cash flow CDO, the collateral is a self-amortiz<strong>in</strong>g pool of high-yield bondsor bank loans, which are usually not traded unless certa<strong>in</strong> credit triggersoccur. The cash flow structure relies on the collateral’s ability to generatesufficient cash to pay pr<strong>in</strong>cipal and <strong>in</strong>terest on the CDO notes. An importantobjective of a cash flow CDO manager is to choose the assets <strong>in</strong> thecollateral pool that will m<strong>in</strong>imize defaults and maximize the couponreturns. Because the collateral pool is not traded actively, the portfolio valueof a cash flow CDO is based on the par amount of the collateral securities.Unlike the case of cash flow CDOs, the collateral of a market valueCDO can be actively traded. As a result, the collateral pool of a marketvalue CDO can be substantially different over time, and <strong>in</strong> this respect marketvalue CDOs are somewhat more similar to a hedge fund than to a traditionalABS structure. Market value CDOs rely on the portfolio manager’sability to generate total returns and liquidate the collateral <strong>in</strong> a timely mannerif deemed necessary to meet the coupon and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments.Because the collateral of market value CDOs is actively traded, marketvalue CDOs are usually marked to market either daily or weekly. The debtrat<strong>in</strong>g of different tranches of a market value CDO depend on the pricevolatility of the assets <strong>in</strong> the collateral pool <strong>in</strong> addition to the diversity andthe credit quality of the pool.Because cash flow and market value CDOs have different portfolioobjectives, the collateral pool of the two CDO structures is somewhat different.For <strong>in</strong>stance, the collateral of cash flow CDOs consists ma<strong>in</strong>ly ofrated high-yield assets and loans that are current. For market value CDOs,on the other hand, the collateral pool is much more diverse and may <strong>in</strong>cludedistressed debt and project f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong> addition to high-yield bonds andloans. The <strong>in</strong>tention of hold<strong>in</strong>g a more diversified collateral pool <strong>in</strong> marketvalue CDOs is to <strong>in</strong>crease the potential returns to <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> the equitytranche. On the liability side, cash flow CDOs tend to have longer liabilitiesthan market value CDOs.


210 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSCash versus Synthetic CDOsCDOs can be characterized as cash or synthetic depend<strong>in</strong>g on whether theCDO <strong>in</strong>vests directly <strong>in</strong> the assets that constitute the collateral through thecash market or <strong>in</strong>vests <strong>in</strong>directly through a credit default swap, total returnswap, or credit-l<strong>in</strong>ked note. In cash CDOs, the assets held as collateral haveto be transferred <strong>in</strong>to a bankruptcy-remote SPV. If the assets <strong>in</strong> the collateralpool comprise bank loans, mov<strong>in</strong>g these loans off balance sheet can be difficult.This is because the bank <strong>in</strong>itiat<strong>in</strong>g this transaction may need to obta<strong>in</strong>permission from the borrower to transfer the ownership of its loans. Thisprocess can be time consum<strong>in</strong>g, expensive, and potentially harmful to customerrelationships. To avoid these problems, synthetic CDOs are used totransfer the credit risk from the balance sheet of the bank. This is achievedthrough a credit default swap structure to transfer out the credit risk of anunderly<strong>in</strong>g basket of loans to a SPV, which are then sold to <strong>in</strong>vestors.A credit default swap structure is similar to an <strong>in</strong>surance policy wherethe buyer purchases protection aga<strong>in</strong>st default risk on a reference pool ofassets that can <strong>in</strong>clude bonds, loans, or other receivables. If the referencepools of assets comprise bank loans, the structure is referred to as a syntheticCLO. The protection buyer <strong>in</strong> a synthetic CDO is usually the bank orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>gthe transaction, and the protection seller is the <strong>in</strong>vestor. The protectionbuyer pays a periodic fee to the protection seller, who <strong>in</strong> turn pays outto the protection buyer if a def<strong>in</strong>ed credit event occurs on the reference poolof assets. Most synthetic CDOs are cash settled, where the protection buyeris paid the difference between par and postdefault market value.Synthetic CDO structures are now widely used <strong>in</strong> both arbitrage andbalance sheet transactions. Structurally, synthetic CDOs have some advantagesover cash CDOs. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> a synthetic CDO there is no <strong>in</strong>terestrate risk because the credit default swap is concerned only with creditevents on the reference pool of assets. If the there is no credit event, the<strong>in</strong>vestors do not face any loss at liquidation even when the reference assetsare worth less due to <strong>in</strong>terest rate changes. Other advantages are that<strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> a synthetic CDO are not dependent on the cash flows from anunderly<strong>in</strong>g pool of bonds or loans and the maturity of the synthetic CDOis governed solely by the maturity of the underly<strong>in</strong>g credit default swap.Investor MotivationsI exam<strong>in</strong>ed the different types of CDOs <strong>in</strong> the market and the motivationfor CDO issuance. Specifically, balance sheet CDOs are <strong>in</strong>tended to provideregulatory capital relief and reduce risk concentrations to particular <strong>in</strong>dustrysectors. Arbitrage CDOs, on the other hand, provide CDO managers astable source of fee <strong>in</strong>come and a share <strong>in</strong> the returns generated by the


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 211equity tranche ownership. In general, creat<strong>in</strong>g a CDO structure <strong>in</strong>volvescosts, and these costs are returns forgone by CDO <strong>in</strong>vestors. In this connection,one may wonder why <strong>in</strong>vestors buy CDOs that cost more than theassets held <strong>in</strong> the CDOs. Investors buy CDOs for a variety of reasons, someof which are as follows.A first and important reason is that the CDO structure creates customexposures that <strong>in</strong>vestors desire and cannot achieve <strong>in</strong> other ways. For<strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong>vestors will<strong>in</strong>g to take exposure to the high-yield market maynot be able to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> this market due to <strong>in</strong>vestment constra<strong>in</strong>ts. To ga<strong>in</strong>access to this asset class, the only opportunity might be to buy a CDOtranche rated <strong>in</strong>vestment grade whose collateral pool conta<strong>in</strong>s high-yieldbonds. Similarly, ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g access to bank loans may only be possible throughCDOs because bank loans are not traded.Other <strong>in</strong>vestor motivations for buy<strong>in</strong>g CDOs <strong>in</strong>clude the follow<strong>in</strong>g:A diversified portfolio can be purchased through one trade execution,which results <strong>in</strong> reduced transaction costs.CDO debt tranches have higher yields than many corporate bonds orasset-backed securities of similar rat<strong>in</strong>g and maturity.Arbitrage CDOs allow <strong>in</strong>vestors to ga<strong>in</strong> exposure to the non-<strong>in</strong>vestmentgrademarket on a highly diversified basis without committ<strong>in</strong>g significantresources.Invest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the equity tranche of the CDO offers the opportunity for aleveraged <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the collateral pool of a diversified portfolio.ANATOMY OF A CDO TRANSACTIONIn the previous section, I discussed the different types of CDOs that areavailable and the motivation beh<strong>in</strong>d their issuance. I also showed that cashCDOs are structured securities whose cash flows stem from the <strong>in</strong>terest andpr<strong>in</strong>cipal <strong>in</strong>come earned on a portfolio of corporate obligations. These obligationsform the CDO collateral, and can comprise banks loans, revolv<strong>in</strong>gloans, corporate bonds, emerg<strong>in</strong>g market debt, and even asset-backed securities.The cash flow from the collateral pool is distributed to the varioustranches follow<strong>in</strong>g a strict priority rule with the more senior tranchesreceiv<strong>in</strong>g payments before the less senior tranches. In this section, I discussthe structure and mechanics of a CDO transaction from the <strong>in</strong>ception stage.Capital StructureA CDO is created us<strong>in</strong>g a standard securitization approach. This <strong>in</strong>volvespool<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>ancial assets and issu<strong>in</strong>g debt and equity obligations backed by


212 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 11.1CDO Capital StructureAssetsLiabilities$100 million: <strong>Corporate</strong> bonds, $80 million: Class A senior notesemerg<strong>in</strong>g market debt,$15 million: Class B mezzan<strong>in</strong>e notesbank loans$5 million: Equitythe pool of assets. The entity that issues the obligations and buys the poolof assets is called special-purpose vehicle (SPV). The SPV is set up as abankruptcy-remote entity, which <strong>in</strong> legal terms means that the CDO<strong>in</strong>vestors are tak<strong>in</strong>g the risks of ownership of the assets but not the additionalrisk of bankruptcy of the CDO’s sponsor. This is achieved by creat<strong>in</strong>gthe SPV as a newly established entity with no operat<strong>in</strong>g history toexclude the scope of hav<strong>in</strong>g prior liabilities. Furthermore, the relevant documentsof the SPV and the CDO must limit the SPV’s activities to thoseessential for the transaction and should prohibit the SPV <strong>in</strong>curr<strong>in</strong>g additionaldebt. The SPV is registered as a charitable trust and is usually established<strong>in</strong> a tax-free jurisdiction.The capital structure of a CDO consists of the collateral pool held <strong>in</strong>the SPV on the asset side and a set of CDO notes hav<strong>in</strong>g different paymentobligations and priorities on the liability side. Exhibit 11.1 shows the typicalcapital structure of a CDO transaction.In Exhibit 11.1, the CDO structure issues a senior note, a mezzan<strong>in</strong>enote, and a subord<strong>in</strong>ated note or equity. This liability structure is createdout of a collateral pool of assets that <strong>in</strong>clude corporate bonds, bank loans,and emerg<strong>in</strong>g market debt. The process by which claims on cash flows generatedby a collateral portfolio are split <strong>in</strong>to an equity share and severalclasses of notes or “tranches” hav<strong>in</strong>g vary<strong>in</strong>g payment priorities is referredto as tranch<strong>in</strong>g. Tranch<strong>in</strong>g transforms a less attractive <strong>in</strong>vestment on thecollateral side <strong>in</strong>to more attractive <strong>in</strong>vestments that appeal to a wider<strong>in</strong>vestor community. This is achieved through subord<strong>in</strong>ation, which is aform of structural credit enhancement. Subord<strong>in</strong>ated CDO debt tranchesprotect more senior debt tranches aga<strong>in</strong>st credit losses, and <strong>in</strong> return forthis, receive a higher coupon for tak<strong>in</strong>g on greater credit risk. In Exhibit 11.1,the senior notes have a subord<strong>in</strong>ation amount of $20 million.The rat<strong>in</strong>g of each CDO tranche depends on its ability to service debtwith the cash flows generated by the assets <strong>in</strong> the collateral pool. The debtservic<strong>in</strong>gability depends on the collateral diversification, subord<strong>in</strong>ation,and structural protection present <strong>in</strong> the CDO structure. The senior CDOnotes are typically rated triple A to s<strong>in</strong>gle A and mezzan<strong>in</strong>e notes are typicallyrated triple B to s<strong>in</strong>gle B. The equity tranche is generally unrated, andreceives all or most of the residual <strong>in</strong>terest proceeds of the collateral.


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 213EXHIBIT 11.2<strong>Credit</strong> Quality Distribution of CDO Capital StructureLiabilitiesAssetsAAA/AaaAA/Aa2A/A2BBB/Baa2BB/Ba2B/B2CCC/CaaNR-100 -75 -50 -25 0 25 50 75 100Clearly, as one moves down the CDO’s capital structure, the level of risk<strong>in</strong>creases. Exhibit 11.2 shows the distribution of the credit quality of theCDO capital structure from an asset–liability perspective.Exhibit 11.2 shows that <strong>in</strong> spite of the fact that the credit quality of theassets <strong>in</strong> the collateral pool is below AA, the senior CDO note has a triple-Arat<strong>in</strong>g. This is possible because of the priority of claims established throughsubord<strong>in</strong>ation. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a default of a s<strong>in</strong>gle bond <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolioreduces the return on the asset side of the CDO structure. However, onthe liability side, the s<strong>in</strong>gle bond default is almost entirely absorbed by theequity tranche. Any loss that cannot be absorbed by the equity tranche ispassed on to the mezzan<strong>in</strong>e tranche. Such a subord<strong>in</strong>ation of claims ensuresthat the promised cash flows to the senior notes will only be affected if severalbonds <strong>in</strong> the collateral pool default dur<strong>in</strong>g the life of the CDO.How the Transaction EvolvesOnce the decision is made to issue a CDO, the asset types and specific creditsto be <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the collateral have to be identified by the asset manager.In most cases, the asset manager starts buy<strong>in</strong>g the assets prior to the clos<strong>in</strong>gdate of the deal with the <strong>in</strong>tention of transferr<strong>in</strong>g the assets <strong>in</strong>to the SPVon the clos<strong>in</strong>g date. This period, also referred to as the warehous<strong>in</strong>g period,requires a bridge facility to f<strong>in</strong>ance the purchase of the assets. The warehous<strong>in</strong>gperiod can last typically several weeks.


214 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSOn the clos<strong>in</strong>g date of the CDO transaction, the SPV issues multipledebt tranches and an equity tranche to <strong>in</strong>vestors. The asset manager thenenters <strong>in</strong>to an <strong>in</strong>vestment management agreement with the SPV to managethe collateral assets. Subsequently, the assets bought dur<strong>in</strong>g the warehous<strong>in</strong>gperiod are transferred to the SPV and the asset manager cont<strong>in</strong>uesacquir<strong>in</strong>g the collateral assets us<strong>in</strong>g the proceeds from the sale of debt andequity tranches. The period dur<strong>in</strong>g which the assets are acquired is referredto as the ramp-up period, and this can last 3 to 6 months. The ramp-upperiod is usually followed by a re<strong>in</strong>vestment period, which could last 3 to6 years. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the re<strong>in</strong>vestment period, the cash flows from pr<strong>in</strong>cipalrepayments aris<strong>in</strong>g from early amortization are re<strong>in</strong>vested.F<strong>in</strong>ally, the re<strong>in</strong>vestment period is followed by an amortization perioddur<strong>in</strong>g which all cash received from repayment of pr<strong>in</strong>cipal is used to redeemthe liabilities. Most CDOs follow a sequential schedule for pr<strong>in</strong>cipal repayments.Under this schedule, the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal of the senior notes is repaid fullybefore the repayment of pr<strong>in</strong>cipal is made to less senior tranches <strong>in</strong> the capitalstructure. Some CDOs also repay pr<strong>in</strong>cipal on a “pro rata” basis, wherepr<strong>in</strong>cipal is repaid pro rata accord<strong>in</strong>g to the size of each tranche.Parties to a CDOThe major parties <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> a CDO transaction <strong>in</strong>clude the asset manager,trustee or custodian, hedge counterparty, and, <strong>in</strong> some cases, a bond <strong>in</strong>surer.This list of parties to a CDO is not exhaustive. Typically, it also <strong>in</strong>volvesadditional parties like the rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies that assign rat<strong>in</strong>gs to the CDOnotes issued and lawyers, structur<strong>in</strong>g experts, and underwriters at the timethe transaction is <strong>in</strong>itiated. Exhibit 11.3 shows the typical contractual relationshipamong various parties <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> a CDO transaction. I nowbriefly discuss the role of each party <strong>in</strong> a CDO transaction.Asset Manager The asset manager plays an important role <strong>in</strong> the structur<strong>in</strong>gof a CDO transaction. Typically, an asset manager’s responsibility <strong>in</strong>cludesselect<strong>in</strong>g assets that form the collateral, determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the tim<strong>in</strong>g of sale andpurchase of subsequent <strong>in</strong>vestments, and assess<strong>in</strong>g the quality and adequacyof the collateral <strong>in</strong> meet<strong>in</strong>g the liabilities. Because the asset manager hasconsiderable flexibility and discretion <strong>in</strong> trad<strong>in</strong>g, his or her skills tend tohave an impact on an arbitrage CDO’s performance. The role of an assetmanager for balance sheet CDOs is rather limited because the assets chosen<strong>in</strong> the collateral pool are the ones the bank wants to sell for regulatory capitalrelief or to reduce risk concentrations.Trustee The trustee or custodian <strong>in</strong> a CDO transaction has a fiduciary responsibilityand is responsible for safe custody of the SPV’s assets and for ensur<strong>in</strong>g


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 215EXHIBIT 11.3Typical CDO Contractual RelationshipAssetManagerTrusteeInterest &Pr<strong>in</strong>cipalUnderly<strong>in</strong>gSecurities(Collateral)Assets soldCashSpecial PurposeVehicle(Issues CDONotes)Fund<strong>in</strong>gSeniorNotesMezzan<strong>in</strong>eNotesHedge Provider(If Needed)Equitycompliance with the CDO’s requirements. This may require ensur<strong>in</strong>g that thevarious collateral tests are met before execut<strong>in</strong>g a trade recommended by theasset manager. The compliance test<strong>in</strong>g for CDOs is usually more complex thanfor typical ABS transactions, which is further complicated when active trad<strong>in</strong>gis done <strong>in</strong> market value CDOs. The trustee issues a monthly report detail<strong>in</strong>gthe status of the CDO and cash distributions made by the CDO.Hedge Counterparty If the collateral assets are primarily fixed-coupon-pay<strong>in</strong>gassets and the CDO notes pay float<strong>in</strong>g rates, hedge counterparties will beneeded to swap the proceeds so that the cash flows of the assets and liabilitiesare matched. In different circumstances, hedge counterparties may alsoprovide currency swaps, tim<strong>in</strong>g hedges, or total return swaps.<strong>Bond</strong> Insurer In some circumstances, if external credit enhancements arerequired to prop up the rat<strong>in</strong>g of a CDO tranche, bond <strong>in</strong>surers may be<strong>in</strong>volved. The bond <strong>in</strong>surer guarantees the payment of pr<strong>in</strong>cipal and <strong>in</strong>tereston one or more of the CDO notes issued. <strong>Bond</strong> <strong>in</strong>surance results <strong>in</strong> areduction <strong>in</strong> the senior tranche yield.Structural ProtectionsThe credit quality of the different debt tranches of the CDO depends on theability of the CDO to withstand the default losses and still be able to pay


216 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSthe promised cash flows. Clearly, the credit quality of the debt tranchesdepends on the credit quality of the collateral assets and the structural protectionspresent <strong>in</strong> the CDO as a function of the seniority of the tranche. Inthis section, I focus on structural protections, which can be broadly classified<strong>in</strong>to three categories: subord<strong>in</strong>ation, collateral quality tests, and collateralcoverage tests.Subord<strong>in</strong>ation I mentioned that the CDO capital structure imposes someform of <strong>in</strong>ternal credit enhancement through subord<strong>in</strong>ation. In practice,one can dist<strong>in</strong>guish between two types of subord<strong>in</strong>ation: priority <strong>in</strong> bankruptcyand priority <strong>in</strong> cash flow tim<strong>in</strong>g. Priority of claims <strong>in</strong> the event ofbankruptcy are always strict, which signifies that proceeds from the liquidationof the collateral assets are first paid to meet the obligations of thesenior debt holder. Any proceeds that rema<strong>in</strong> after meet<strong>in</strong>g this claim aredistributed to the debt tranche that is second most senior. This procedure isused until all the proceeds are distributed to the various <strong>in</strong>vestor groups follow<strong>in</strong>gthis strict priority rule.In order to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> tranche priority <strong>in</strong> cash flows, CDOs may use thesequential or pro rata pr<strong>in</strong>cipal paydown mechanism discussed earlier. Thesequential paydown structure has the effect of amortiz<strong>in</strong>g the senior CDOtranches first because pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments are made before the mezzan<strong>in</strong>e orlower tranches are amortized. A variant of this is to use a fast-pay/slow-paystructure <strong>in</strong> which a greater proportion of pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments goes to thesenior tranche.Collateral Quality Tests The collateral quality tests for cash flow CDOs<strong>in</strong>clude a list of criteria that the collateral portfolio must meet on anongo<strong>in</strong>g basis. Each of the collateral quality tests is designed by rat<strong>in</strong>gagencies to ensure that the collateral assets <strong>in</strong> the SPV are managedunder the guidel<strong>in</strong>es mandated by the transaction’s rat<strong>in</strong>g. To someextent, these quality tests depend on the type of assets that comprise thecollateral portfolio. The commonly used collateral quality tests are asfollows:M<strong>in</strong>imum average rat<strong>in</strong>g test. This test specifies that the m<strong>in</strong>imumweighted average rat<strong>in</strong>g of the collateral portfolio must meet a specifiedlevel, which is usually B to B <strong>in</strong> cash flow CDOs.M<strong>in</strong>imum recovery test. This test specifies that the collateral portfoliomeet a m<strong>in</strong>imum weighted average recovery rate.Industry concentration limit. This limit is specified to ensure that thereis sufficient diversification <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio. A typical maximum<strong>in</strong>dustry concentration limit is 8 percent, which is determ<strong>in</strong>ed bythe ratio of the total outstand<strong>in</strong>g par amount of collateral securities <strong>in</strong>


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 217a given <strong>in</strong>dustry divided by the total outstand<strong>in</strong>g par amount of thecollateral.Weighted average maturity test. This test is designed to ensure thatthere is a predictable amortization profile for the rated securities afterthe re<strong>in</strong>vestment period.Collateral Coverage Tests Collateral coverage tests are designed to protect therated notes of cash flow CDOs and serve as early warn<strong>in</strong>g signals that <strong>in</strong>terestor pr<strong>in</strong>cipal proceeds may be <strong>in</strong>adequate to meet the payment obligations.When the coverage tests are not met, cash flows are diverted from lowerrated notes and equity to pay down the more senior CDO tranches, trigger<strong>in</strong>gan early amortization schedule of the senior CDO tranches. Thereare two types of coverage tests commonly used: <strong>in</strong>terest coverage tests andovercollateralization tests.The <strong>in</strong>terest coverage (IC) test is designed to ensure that coupon paymentsreceived from the collateral assets are adequate to pay fees and <strong>in</strong>terestdue on the rated CDO notes. IC tests are usually not employed <strong>in</strong> marketvalue CDOs. 1The overcollateralization (OC) test is designed to ensure that the CDOtransaction ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s a preset m<strong>in</strong>imum overcollateralization ratio for eachrated tranche. The overcollateralization ratio for any tranche is the ratio ofthe par amount of the tranche to the par amount of the perform<strong>in</strong>g assets<strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio plus the expected recovery rate on any defaultedsecurities. OC tests are employed <strong>in</strong> market value CDOs as well, with thetests be<strong>in</strong>g performed on the basis of the market value of the securities<strong>in</strong>stead of par values.To illustrate the procedure <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> comput<strong>in</strong>g IC and OC tests, considera collateral portfolio with a par value of $100 million and a weightedaverage coupon of 8 percent per annum. Let the annual fees, which <strong>in</strong>cludetrustee fees, hedg<strong>in</strong>g premiums, and asset management fees, be $0.5 million.Assume that there are three debt tranches pay<strong>in</strong>g semiannual coupons, thedetails of which are shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 11.4.EXHIBIT 11.4Liability Structure of a CDO aPar Value Annual M<strong>in</strong> IC M<strong>in</strong> OCTranche (mn $) Coupon Ratio (%) Ratio (%)Class A P A 75 C A 5% 150 125Class B P B 10 C B 6% 130 115Class C P C 10 C C 8% 110 100Equity P E 5 — — —a IC, Interest coverage test; OC, Overcollateralization test.


218 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSIC Tests:IC class A P pool WAC FeesP A C A 200%IC class B P pool WAC FeesP A C A P B C B 172%IC class C OC Tests:OC class B OC class C P pool WAC FeesP A C A P B C B P C C C 146%OC class A P poolP A 133%P poolP A P B 118%P poolP A P B P C 105%In these equations, P pool denotes the par amount of the collateral pool andWAC the weighted average coupon of the collateral pool. Note that all thecoverage tests are passed for the this example.MAJOR SOURCES OF RISK IN CDOSAs is the case with any complex f<strong>in</strong>ancial product, <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> CDOs<strong>in</strong>volve risks aris<strong>in</strong>g from a variety of sources. The effective management ofthese risks by the asset manager has a significant <strong>in</strong>fluence on the performanceof the CDO tranches. Among the different sources of risk, the dom<strong>in</strong>antrisk <strong>in</strong> a CDO transaction arises from credit risk. In general, credit riskmanifests itself <strong>in</strong> different forms as a result of various structural protectionmechanisms built <strong>in</strong>to the CDO structure. In this section, I discuss the differenttypes of risks that are commonly associated with CDO transactions.Interest Rate <strong>Risk</strong>Interest rate risk <strong>in</strong> a CDO can arise from a variety of sources, and to someextent will also depend on the complexity of the structure. An importantsource of <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk is the mismatch between coupon receipts andcoupon payments. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the assets <strong>in</strong> the collateral pool might pay


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 219fixed-rate coupons, whereas the CDO might pay float<strong>in</strong>g-rate coupons onthe liabilities. This source of <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk can be usually hedged throughan <strong>in</strong>terest rate swap. Other <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk sources result from the differences<strong>in</strong> the periodicity of coupon receipts and coupon payments and thedifferences <strong>in</strong> coupon payment dates between assets and liabilities.Changes to <strong>in</strong>terest rates can also result <strong>in</strong> significant risks to the CDO.For <strong>in</strong>stance, if the collateral portfolio <strong>in</strong>cludes a greater proportion of callablebonds, fall<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest rates can lead to large pr<strong>in</strong>cipal prepayments, and thesehave to be re<strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> a lower yield<strong>in</strong>g asset. Hedg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk fullyis usually difficult <strong>in</strong> CDO transactions due to the active management of thecollateral assets and embedded optionalities that may be present <strong>in</strong> them.Liquidity <strong>Risk</strong>The collateral pool of CDOs <strong>in</strong>cludes high-yield and emerg<strong>in</strong>g marketbonds. Because bonds belong<strong>in</strong>g to these asset classes have limited liquidity,CDOs that <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> these asset classes are exposed to liquidity risk. Theimplication is that the asset manager may not be able to liquidate the assetswhen needed. In particular, if some of the illiquid assets mature after thelegal maturity of the CDO, liquidity risk may have a negative impact on thereturn of the equity <strong>in</strong>vestor. 2 From an <strong>in</strong>vestor’s perspective, the limitedscope for secondary market trad<strong>in</strong>g of CDOs leads to liquidity risk.Ramp-Up <strong>Risk</strong>Arbitrage CDO transactions <strong>in</strong>volve an <strong>in</strong>itial period, known as a ramp-upperiod, dur<strong>in</strong>g which a significant portfolio of the collateral assets isacquired. This ramp-up period can last from 3 to 6 months after the CDOnotes are issued to <strong>in</strong>vestors. The extent of ramp-up risk <strong>in</strong> a CDO transactiondepends on the relative proportion of assets acquired dur<strong>in</strong>g theramp-up period and how long it lasts. The major risks that arise dur<strong>in</strong>g theramp-up period <strong>in</strong>clude the follow<strong>in</strong>g:Negative carry between the earn<strong>in</strong>gs on cash deposits and the liabilitiesdue on CDO notes.Orig<strong>in</strong>ation risk due to unavailability of bonds the asset manager<strong>in</strong>tended to buy.Adverse credit spread or price movements, which <strong>in</strong>crease the cost ofbuy<strong>in</strong>g the collateral assets.Re<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>Risk</strong>The CDO assets are allowed to be traded dur<strong>in</strong>g the re<strong>in</strong>vestment period,which can last 3 to 6 years, provided the collateral coverage and quality


220 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOStests are met. Re<strong>in</strong>vestment of collateral cash flows provides the flexibilityto ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> collateral quality and portfolio diversification as rat<strong>in</strong>gchanges, defaults, and early amortizations reconfigure the collateral pool’srisk–return profile. Replac<strong>in</strong>g the bonds <strong>in</strong> the collateral pool gives rise tore<strong>in</strong>vestment risk. For <strong>in</strong>stance, if a bond matures and the <strong>in</strong>terest rateshave decl<strong>in</strong>ed s<strong>in</strong>ce the issuance of the CDO notes, the proceeds have to be<strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> a lower yield<strong>in</strong>g asset, caus<strong>in</strong>g the excess spread to be lower. 3 Inother <strong>in</strong>stances, the asset manager may have to <strong>in</strong>vest the proceeds <strong>in</strong> shortterm<strong>in</strong>struments until suitable <strong>in</strong>vestment opportunities are identified. Dur<strong>in</strong>gthis period, the CDO will be exposed to negative carry due to <strong>in</strong>vestments<strong>in</strong> a low-yield<strong>in</strong>g asset. Negative carry usually affects the return onthe CDO’s equity tranche.Prepayment <strong>Risk</strong>Prepayment risk arises from early amortization triggers result<strong>in</strong>g from collateralcoverage tests not be<strong>in</strong>g met. This risk is enhanced <strong>in</strong> transactionsthat have tighter collateral coverage ratios. Prepayment risk is mostly borneby the senior note holders <strong>in</strong> a CDO transaction because the payment waterfall<strong>in</strong> arbitrage CDOs is mostly sequential. However, when a collateral coveragetest is not passed, it will not automatically result <strong>in</strong> a prepayment. Thisis because senior notes are repaid from pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments. If there is nopr<strong>in</strong>cipal payment dur<strong>in</strong>g a period, prepayment to senior debt holders willbe deferred until pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments on the collateral assets are due.Asset Manager <strong>Risk</strong>The performance of the various tranches of an arbitrage CDO are strongly<strong>in</strong>fluenced by the trad<strong>in</strong>g practices and expertise of the asset manager.Specifically, the asset manager’s decisions regard<strong>in</strong>g choice of portfolio compositionand tim<strong>in</strong>g of sale and purchase of assets have an important <strong>in</strong>fluenceon the CDO’s performance. Moreover, the asset manager’s decisionregard<strong>in</strong>g how to balance the <strong>in</strong>terests of equity stake holders and debtholders <strong>in</strong> the CDO may also be crucial to the CDO performance. For<strong>in</strong>stance, part of the excess spread could be paid to equity holders early <strong>in</strong>the life of the CDO provided no collateral quality and coverage tests areviolated. This leakage of collateral value, however, may not be <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terestsof the debt holders. In other cases, the asset manager may purchaseassets trad<strong>in</strong>g at a discount to par <strong>in</strong> order to boost the return to equitystakeholders because it <strong>in</strong>creases the par value of the collateral assets. Suchan <strong>in</strong>vestment, from the debt holders’ perspective, will be seen as a creditdeterioration of the collateral pool because they do not participate <strong>in</strong> theequity’s upside potential.


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 221RATING A CDO TRANSACTIONThe rat<strong>in</strong>gs assigned to the different tranches of a CDO transaction arel<strong>in</strong>ked to the ability of the structure to make timely payments of <strong>in</strong>terest andpr<strong>in</strong>cipal on the outstand<strong>in</strong>g liabilities. This requires model<strong>in</strong>g the risksassociated with future cash flows by tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account the subord<strong>in</strong>ationstructure, default rates, recovery amounts, and default correlation betweenthe issuers <strong>in</strong> the collateral pool of the CDO. If one <strong>in</strong>troduces an additionallevel of complexity where the composition of the collateral assets changeover time, model<strong>in</strong>g the cash flow risks over the life of a CDO transactionbecomes almost <strong>in</strong>tractable. This is particularly true for market valueCDOs, which tend to be actively traded. Even <strong>in</strong> the case of cash flowCDOs, asset managers are given limited freedom to trade the collateralassets. This may be driven by the motivation to reduce further losses on“credit-impaired” assets or to take profit from “credit-improved” assets.Such trades result <strong>in</strong> a change <strong>in</strong> the cash flow characteristics of the underly<strong>in</strong>gcollateral pool, and, as a consequence, the cash flow risk profile of thenew collateral pool can be quite different.Different trad<strong>in</strong>g practices followed by asset managers can also <strong>in</strong>troduceadditional risks to a CDO transaction. For <strong>in</strong>stance, some asset managersmay pursue “par build<strong>in</strong>g” trades to enhance the return for equitytranche holders. 4 This refers to the practice of purchas<strong>in</strong>g deeply discountedbonds and sell<strong>in</strong>g par or premium bonds because the collateral coveragetests for cash flow CDOs are based on the par value of the bond rather thanmarket values. Another related asset manager risk arises from how the assetmanager employs the excess spread present <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio. If theexcess spread is employed to buy additional collateral, this can enhance thecredit protection available to senior note holders.The discussion suggests that rat<strong>in</strong>g any tranche of a CDO transactionis a rather complex process. It is complex because the asset pool changesdur<strong>in</strong>g the life of the transaction result<strong>in</strong>g from a number of factors: prepayments,collateral triggers, re<strong>in</strong>vestment of cash flows and excess spread,and trad<strong>in</strong>g actions result<strong>in</strong>g from qualitative decisions taken by asset managers.Model<strong>in</strong>g the risks associated with the cash flows of a collateral poolthat changes over time is usually <strong>in</strong>tractable. Therefore, model<strong>in</strong>g the cashflow risks of the CDO structure can only be done with respect to the currentcomposition of the collateral pool.The general approach taken by rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies for assign<strong>in</strong>g a creditrat<strong>in</strong>g to a particular CDO tranche is a function of the expected loss associatedwith the tranche after tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account the cash flow priorities.Many alternative methods can be used for estimat<strong>in</strong>g the expected loss,rang<strong>in</strong>g from Monte Carlo simulation techniques to simple credit-eventdrivenscenario analysis. 5 The technique used to compute the expected loss


222 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSof a given tranche differs among the different rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies. In this section,I briefly describe the different approaches used by rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies torate a CDO tranche.Moody’s MethodMoody’s rat<strong>in</strong>g methodology for cash flow CDOs compares the credit risk<strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio with the credit protection offered by thestructure to different tranches. The CDO’s credit protection is quantified <strong>in</strong>terms of the maximum collateral loss the structure is able to withstandwithout affect<strong>in</strong>g the cash flows of the rated notes. In determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g anappropriate rat<strong>in</strong>g for the various CDO tranches, Moody’s evaluates thecollateral portfolio’s credit risk and the credit protections present <strong>in</strong> the CDOstructure. Because the rat<strong>in</strong>g of the CDO tranche is based on the expectedloss concept, the first step <strong>in</strong> the rat<strong>in</strong>gs process is to model the credit risk ofthe collateral portfolio. Rather than model<strong>in</strong>g correlated credit events,Moody’s approach transforms the actual pool of collateral assets <strong>in</strong>to apool of uncorrelated assets through a concept known as the diversity score.Stated simply, the diversity score represents the equivalent number ofuncorrelated assets <strong>in</strong> a comparison portfolio that exhibits a similar degreeof default risk as the orig<strong>in</strong>al portfolio with correlated assets. Moody’smake the further assumption that the probability of default of each obligor<strong>in</strong> the comparison portfolio is identical us<strong>in</strong>g a weighted average rat<strong>in</strong>gfactor. The estimate of the expected loss of the collateral portfolio is thenderived based on the assumption that the loss distribution of a portfolioof uncorrelated assets follows a b<strong>in</strong>omial distribution. I briefly describehere Moody’s methodology, referred to as a b<strong>in</strong>om<strong>in</strong>al expansion technique(BET), for determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of a cash flow CDOtranche.B<strong>in</strong>omial Expansion Technique As mentioned earlier, Moody’s approach consists<strong>in</strong> transform<strong>in</strong>g a collateral pool of correlated assets <strong>in</strong>to a pool of uncorrelatedassets through the diversity score concept. The diversity score of apool of correlated assets is computed by exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the degree of diversificationto various <strong>in</strong>dustries present <strong>in</strong> the asset pool. Moody’s def<strong>in</strong>e a listof 33 <strong>in</strong>dustry categories, and the default risk between two obligors belong<strong>in</strong>gto different <strong>in</strong>dustry groups is assumed to be uncorrelated. The diversityscore for a two-obligor portfolio where both obligors belong to the same<strong>in</strong>dustry is def<strong>in</strong>ed to be equal to 1.5. Exhibit 11.5 shows how Moody’sassigns the diversity score as an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g number of assets <strong>in</strong> the collateralportfolio belong to the same <strong>in</strong>dustry group.The collateral portfolio’s diversity score is computed by summ<strong>in</strong>g thediversity scores of all <strong>in</strong>dustries represented <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. For purposes


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 223EXHIBIT 11.5Moody’s Diversity ScoreNumber of Firms <strong>in</strong>Same IndustryDiversity Score1 1.002 1.503 2.004 2.335 2.676 3.007 3.258 3.509 3.7510 4.00Source: Adapted from Table 4 <strong>in</strong> Alan Backmanand Gerard O’Connor, “Rat<strong>in</strong>g Cash FlowTransactions Backed by <strong>Corporate</strong> Debt 1995Update,” Moody’s Investors Service, April1995, p. 11. © Moody’s Investors Service, Inc.,and/or its affiliates. Repr<strong>in</strong>ted with permission.All rights reserved.of illustration, if the collateral portfolio comprises 30 bonds belong<strong>in</strong>g to30 different <strong>in</strong>dustries, the diversity score is 30. On the other hand, ifthere are only 10 <strong>in</strong>dustries represented <strong>in</strong> the portfolio with groups ofthree bonds belong<strong>in</strong>g to a particular <strong>in</strong>dustry category, then the diversityscore of this portfolio is only 20. Notice that a higher diversity scorecorresponds to a greater diversification <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio. Theforego<strong>in</strong>g diversity score calculation makes the assumption that the paramounts for the bonds <strong>in</strong> the portfolio are equal. Moody’s adjusts thediversity score if the par amounts of the bonds <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolioare not equal.Apart from comput<strong>in</strong>g the diversity score for the portfolio, the defaultprobabilities of the <strong>in</strong>dividual assets <strong>in</strong> the portfolio have to be specified <strong>in</strong>order to estimate the expected loss of the comparison portfolio. Aga<strong>in</strong>,Moody’s makes the simplify<strong>in</strong>g assumption that the default probabilities ofevery asset <strong>in</strong> the comparison portfolio are equal to some average probabilityof default. The average probability of default is <strong>in</strong>ferred by first comput<strong>in</strong>ga weighted average rat<strong>in</strong>g factor (WARF) for the collateral portfolio.This requires transform<strong>in</strong>g the letter rat<strong>in</strong>g of the bond obligor <strong>in</strong>to anequivalent numeric rat<strong>in</strong>g factor. The numeric rat<strong>in</strong>g factors used byMoody’s are given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 11.6. If A i denotes the par amount of the ithbond <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio and RF i its correspond<strong>in</strong>g rat<strong>in</strong>g factor, then


224 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 11.6<strong>Credit</strong> Rat<strong>in</strong>gMoodys’s Rat<strong>in</strong>g FactorsRat<strong>in</strong>g FactorAaa 1Aa1 10Aa2 20Aa3 40A1 70A2 120A3 180Baa1 260Baa2 360Baa3 610Ba1 940Ba2 1,350Ba3 1,780B1 2,220B2 2,720B3 3,490Caa 6,500Ca–C 10,000Source: Adapted from Table 8 <strong>in</strong> Alan Backmanand Gerard O’Connor, “Rat<strong>in</strong>g Cash FlowTransactions Backed by <strong>Corporate</strong> Debt 1995Update,” Moody’s Investors Service, April1995, p. 18. © Moody’s Investors Service, Inc.,and/or its affiliates. Repr<strong>in</strong>ted with permission.All rights reserved.the WARF of an n-bond collateral portfolio is given byWARF na A i RF ii1na A ii1(11.1)Given the WARF for the collateral portfolio, one can assign an averageprobability of default p over the life of the CDO that reflects the historicalcumulative probability of default for the rat<strong>in</strong>g. For <strong>in</strong>stance, if the WARF forthe collateral portfolio is equal to 280, then p can be set equal to the cumulativeprobability of default of a Baa2-rated issuer over the life of the CDO.Given a diversity score D and a cumulative probability of default p forthe comparison portfolio, the probability of k defaults dur<strong>in</strong>g the life of the


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 225CDO is given by the follow<strong>in</strong>g b<strong>in</strong>omial distribution:P k D!(D k)! pk (1 p) Dk(11.2)To compute the expected loss of a particular CDO tranche, we need tocompute the tranche loss L k when k defaults occur <strong>in</strong> the comparison portfolio.Comput<strong>in</strong>g L k for any tranche requires tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account the waterfallstructure, the credit protections available <strong>in</strong> the CDO structure, and theassumed recovery rates for the assets <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio. Given P kand L k , the expected loss for the tranche can be computed as follows:expected loss aDk1P k L k(11.3)Once the expected loss for a given CDO tranche is computed, the impliedcumulative default probability of the tranche can be computed, given a certa<strong>in</strong>recovery rate assumption, as follows:cumulative default probability expected loss/(1 recovery rate) (11.4)Given an estimate of the cumulative probability of default, the impliedcredit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the CDO tranche can be estimated us<strong>in</strong>g Moody’s idealizedcumulative probability of defaults estimated for different rat<strong>in</strong>gs as a functionof the maturity of the security. 6 In practice, the cumulative defaultprobabilities are multiplied by a stress factor before the actual mapp<strong>in</strong>g toa credit rat<strong>in</strong>g is done.In assign<strong>in</strong>g a credit rat<strong>in</strong>g to a specific CDO tranche, Moody’s doesnot rely exclusively on a quantitative valuation framework. Instead, thequantitative factors are evaluated <strong>in</strong> conjunction with qualitative factorssuch as asset manager risk and the legal and structural risks <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> theCDO transaction before rat<strong>in</strong>g a CDO tranche.Rat<strong>in</strong>g Market Value CDOs In a market value CDO, the asset manager hasmuch more freedom <strong>in</strong> trad<strong>in</strong>g the collateral assets. To take this <strong>in</strong>to consideration,the collateral coverage tests are performed us<strong>in</strong>g the marketvalue of the collateral portfolio rather than the par value as <strong>in</strong> the case ofcash flow CDOs. The market value of the collateral portfolio is <strong>in</strong>fluencedby a variety of factors, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g changes <strong>in</strong> credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the collateralassets, changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest rates, changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestor preferences that result<strong>in</strong> changes to credit spreads, and, f<strong>in</strong>ally, the actual defaults that can occurto the collateral assets. Because an important additional source of risk <strong>in</strong> a


226 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSmarket value CDO is the price volatility of the collateral portfolio if marketvalues are used for collateral coverage tests, Moody’s takes <strong>in</strong>to accountthe price volatility <strong>in</strong> the rat<strong>in</strong>g process through a set of advance rates.Advance rates can be described as the adjustments that need to be madeto the value of each asset so as to provide a cushion aga<strong>in</strong>st market risk.Specifically, the overcollateralization test described earlier is carried out onthe market value of the collateral assets discounted by an appropriateadvance rate. Thus, advance rates can be seen as represent<strong>in</strong>g “haircuts”that provide credit enhancement for the rated CDO note. Advance ratesvary by asset type: Assets with greater price volatility require lower advancerates. The degree of diversification present <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio alsoaffects advance rates; a portfolio with greater diversification has higheradvance rates.Moody’s approach to choos<strong>in</strong>g the advance rates is based primarily onhistorical simulations. However, <strong>in</strong> cases where historical data are limited,the volatility of asset returns and correlation between assets are usuallyadjusted upward. Once an appropriate advance rate is calculated and thecollateral asset values are properly discounted to account for the collateralportfolio’s volatility, the method used for <strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>g the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of theCDO tranche is very similar to the case of the cash flow CDO.Standard & Poor’s MethodThe approach taken by Standard & Poor’s to rate the different CDOtranches gives greater emphasis to model<strong>in</strong>g the correlation between assetreturns of various obligors <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio. In this respect, the rat<strong>in</strong>gapproach of Standard & Poor’s is fundamentally different fromMoody’s approach. Standard & Poor’s rat<strong>in</strong>g process <strong>in</strong>volves three ma<strong>in</strong>steps. First, the default rate distribution of the collateral portfolio over thelife of the CDO is generated. Second, a set of scenario default rates (SDRs)for different tranches based on the default rate distribution of the collateralportfolio is derived. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the cash flow analysis of the CDO transactionis carried out <strong>in</strong> conjunction with the calculated SDRs to determ<strong>in</strong>e theappropriate rat<strong>in</strong>gs for the various tranches. I briefly describe this three-stepprocess <strong>in</strong> rat<strong>in</strong>g a CDO tranche.Default Rate Distribution Consider<strong>in</strong>g that the CDO rat<strong>in</strong>g is ultimately l<strong>in</strong>kedto the probability of jo<strong>in</strong>t defaults of the collateral portfolio, an estimate ofthe default rate distribution is an important <strong>in</strong>put variable. To generate thedefault rate distribution of the collateral portfolio, Standard & Poor’s usesa proprietary model called the CDO Evaluator. 7 This proprietary modeluses the Monte Carlo simulation technique to generate the probability distributionof default rates as a percentage of the total pr<strong>in</strong>cipal balance for


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 227the collateral portfolio. The default rate simulation takes <strong>in</strong>to considerationthe credit rat<strong>in</strong>g, the size and the maturity of each asset, and the asset returncorrelation between the assets <strong>in</strong> the collateral portfolio. Standard & Poor’smakes the follow<strong>in</strong>g assumptions for simulat<strong>in</strong>g the default rate distributionof the collateral portfolio:The asset return correlation between corporate obligors is taken to be.3 if the obligors belong to the same <strong>in</strong>dustry sector. The asset returncorrelation between corporate obligors that do not belong to the same<strong>in</strong>dustry sector is considered to be zero (there are 39 <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors <strong>in</strong>Standard & Poor’s <strong>in</strong>dustry classification).The default rates of the assets are differentiated by asset type, maturity,and credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the obligor. For example, the asset default rate fora triple-A-rated corporate bond matur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 4 years is set to be 0.19percent, whereas for a triple-B-rated corporate bond with the samematurity this is set to be 21.45 percent. The choice of these default ratesis based on Standard & Poor’s default study of corporate obligors.Scenario Default Rates Once the default rate distribution of the collateralportfolio over the life of the CDO transaction has been simulated, Standard &Poor’s computes an <strong>in</strong>dicative tranche size for a given target credit rat<strong>in</strong>g.This is done by deriv<strong>in</strong>g the scenario default rate that is applicable to thetarget credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the tranche. The SDR represents the default rate thatthe CDO tranche with a given credit rat<strong>in</strong>g should be able to withstandunder various cash flow scenarios modeled by Standard & Poor’s rat<strong>in</strong>g criteria.The determ<strong>in</strong>ation of the SDR is done through a two-step process. Inthe first step, a trial SDR is derived from the default rate distribution. Thisis done by first identify<strong>in</strong>g the default rate for a corporate bond hav<strong>in</strong>g thesame tranche credit rat<strong>in</strong>g and weighted average maturity of the collateralportfolio. Subsequently, the portfolio default rate that will not be exceededby more than this identified default rate for the corporate bond is chosen tobe the trial SDR. This process is best expla<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g Exhibit 11.7, whichshows the typical shape of the simulated portfolio default rates for a transactionhav<strong>in</strong>g weighted average maturity of 10 years.From Exhibit 11.7, one can <strong>in</strong>fer that there is a 1 percent chance thatthe default rate on the collateral portfolio will exceed 30 percent dur<strong>in</strong>g thelife of the CDO transaction. Because the default rate of 1 percent over a10-year period is the historical cumulative probability of default of a triple-A-rated corporate bond, the trial SDR is equal to 30 percent for the CDOtranche with triple-A rat<strong>in</strong>g. This simple example provides the motivationfor <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g the SDRs for various tranches: It makes it possible todeterm<strong>in</strong>e the respective tranche sizes and their correspond<strong>in</strong>g credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs.In this example, an SDR of 30 percent corresponds to an <strong>in</strong>itial estimate of


228 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSEXHIBIT 11.7Probability Distribution of Portfolio Default Rates0.200.16Probability0.120.080.041% probability of default rate exceed<strong>in</strong>g 30%0.000% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%Default rate (% of total pr<strong>in</strong>cipal balance)the triple-A tranche size to be 70 percent of the par value of the collateralassets.The <strong>in</strong>itial estimate of the SDR is ref<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the second step by multiply<strong>in</strong>git by an adjustment factor. Standard & Poor’s does not provide details ofhow these adjustment factors are computed. For a triple-A-rated tranche, theadjustment factor is 1.20, and this leads to the f<strong>in</strong>al SDR of 36 percent. 8 Basedon this SDR, the <strong>in</strong>dicative tranche size for a triple-A rat<strong>in</strong>g should not exceed64 percent (100 percent m<strong>in</strong>us 36 percent) for this collateral portfolio.Cash Flow Analysis Once the SDR for a target tranche credit rat<strong>in</strong>g has beenderived, a cash flow analysis is carried out tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account all the structuralelements of the transaction. The purpose of this exercise is to verifythat each CDO tranche can cont<strong>in</strong>ue to pay pr<strong>in</strong>cipal and <strong>in</strong>terest notwithstand<strong>in</strong>gdefaults up to the SDR on the collateral portfolio. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the cashflow analysis, recoveries on the defaulted debt and tim<strong>in</strong>g of defaults aretaken <strong>in</strong>to account. The f<strong>in</strong>al size of the CDO tranches are selected throughan iterative procedure where the tranche size is <strong>in</strong>creased as long as its lossesare lower than the SDR for the tranche.Method of Fitch Rat<strong>in</strong>gsThe rat<strong>in</strong>g methodology of Fitch for cash flow CDOs shares many similaritieswith Moody’s approach. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the CDO tranche’s expected lossis used to derive the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g for the tranche, a practice also followedby Moody’s. However, an important difference between Moody’s approach


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 229and the Fitch approach is that Fitch does not use the diversity score conceptand the b<strong>in</strong>omial expansion technique to derive the cumulative probabilityof default. Instead, Fitch simulates the cash flows specific to the transactionand takes <strong>in</strong>to account the tim<strong>in</strong>g of defaults, <strong>in</strong>terest rate risks, andassumptions on recovery rates and default probabilities. These simulationsare also used to determ<strong>in</strong>e the appropriate level of credit enhancementsrequired to support the CDO tranche rat<strong>in</strong>g.In rat<strong>in</strong>g different tranches of the CDO, Fitch’s method focuses on thefollow<strong>in</strong>g issues:When evaluat<strong>in</strong>g asset managers, Fitch looks for strong credit underwrit<strong>in</strong>gskills and demonstrated ability to manage portfolios throughcredit cycles. Superior portfolio management skills are evaluated byexam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the stability of risk-adjusted ratios generated over time onmanaged portfolios aga<strong>in</strong>st an <strong>in</strong>dex by the asset manager. Evaluationof asset manager skills dur<strong>in</strong>g the rat<strong>in</strong>g process reflects the op<strong>in</strong>ion ofFitch that asset manager skills play an important role <strong>in</strong> the overall performanceof the CDO transaction.Collateral quality tests are based on the weighted average rat<strong>in</strong>g factorfor the collateral portfolio us<strong>in</strong>g Fitch rat<strong>in</strong>g factors, which are differentfrom Moody’s rat<strong>in</strong>g factors. 9 In recognition of the fact that weightedaverage rat<strong>in</strong>gs can change over time result<strong>in</strong>g from credit migration,Fitch permits asset managers to freely trade the collateral even for cashflow CDOs. However, Fitch requires that the weighted average rat<strong>in</strong>gand weighted average coupon values specified <strong>in</strong> the CDO guidel<strong>in</strong>edocumentation are not violated when collateral is traded.Concern<strong>in</strong>g collateral diversification, Fitch takes the view that enforc<strong>in</strong>gexplicit requirements on <strong>in</strong>dustry diversification may be counterproductive.This is because such a requirement may force asset managersto take exposures to certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors that they do not feel comfortablewith. Moreover, the strong positive asset return correlationbetween obligors belong<strong>in</strong>g to different <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors limits thepotential diversification benefits. As a result of these observations, Fitchrequires only a m<strong>in</strong>imum of 10 <strong>in</strong>dustry exposures. Among these 10<strong>in</strong>dustry exposures, exposures to 3 <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors are allowed toexceed the 10 percent exposure limit provided the total exposure to the3 <strong>in</strong>dustries does not exceed 35 percent.Structural protections are enforced through overcollateralization and<strong>in</strong>terest coverage tests. For nondefaulted assets, these tests are based onthe par value of the assets. Defaulted assets, on the other hand, are valuedat the lower of the recovery assumption for the asset class and the marketvalue of the asset. Interest coverage tests are performed as frequently ascoupon payments are made and whenever the collateral assets are traded.


230 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSTRADABLE CORPORATE BOND BASKETSA major concern of many <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> corporate bonds is the lack of liquidity<strong>in</strong> the corporate bond market compared to the government bondmarket. Institutional fixed-<strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>vestors, <strong>in</strong> particular, would like tohave the option to execute large buy or sell orders for corporate bondswithout <strong>in</strong>curr<strong>in</strong>g significant transaction costs. Unfortunately, the averageissue size for many corporate bonds is <strong>in</strong> the range $300 to $500 millionand hence deal sizes for many corporate bonds are typically <strong>in</strong> the regionof $10 million. As a consequence, <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>vestors wish<strong>in</strong>g to take onor shed sizable diversified corporate credit exposures are exposed to significantliquidity risk. To address this concern, major <strong>in</strong>vestment bankshave issued securities that are backed by a portfolio of corporate bondsthat can be traded us<strong>in</strong>g one deal execution. Examples of such tradablecorporate bond baskets <strong>in</strong>clude Morgan Stanley’s Tradable CustodialReceipts (Tracers) and Lehman Brothers Targeted Return Index Securities(Tra<strong>in</strong>s). 10 Tracers and Tra<strong>in</strong>s are designed to balance the liquidity concernswith the need to represent the broad <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade bond market.The average lot sizes for these products are around $100 million, which isquite attractive from the perspective of large <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>vestors. Animportant difference between tradable bond baskets and CDOs backed bya portfolio of corporate bonds is that tradable bond baskets are nottranched.Other examples of tradable corporate bond baskets <strong>in</strong>clude the iSharesGS $ InvesTop exchange-traded fund (ETF) launched by Barclays GlobalInvestors, which is <strong>in</strong>dexed to a portfolio consist<strong>in</strong>g of 100 <strong>in</strong>vestmentgradecorporate bonds denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong> U.S. dollars. Because it is exchangetraded, it allows <strong>in</strong>vestors to take short positions and execute limit orders.Furthermore, transaction costs are lower compared to tak<strong>in</strong>g a similardiversified exposure through mutual funds. As a result of this flexibility, themajor <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> this fund <strong>in</strong>clude hedge funds and retail <strong>in</strong>vestors. However,the <strong>in</strong>vestment guidel<strong>in</strong>es of many <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>vestors do not permitthem to buy this fund because ETFs trade as a stock. As of April 2003,the outstand<strong>in</strong>g amount of the iShares corporate bond fund was close to$2 billion.In the follow<strong>in</strong>g sections, I focus primarily on Tracers issued <strong>in</strong> thecash market backed by a portfolio of <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bonds. Iprovide a brief description of the characteristics of Tracers and expla<strong>in</strong>how <strong>in</strong>vestors can assess the relative value of this structured product comparedto buy<strong>in</strong>g a s<strong>in</strong>gle corporate bond with similar credit rat<strong>in</strong>g and marketrisk characteristics. In connection with this, I discuss a technique for<strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>g the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of Tracers and similar structured creditproducts.


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 231Ma<strong>in</strong> Features of TracersTracers are custody receipts that represent an ownership <strong>in</strong>terest on a prorata basis <strong>in</strong> an equal par-weighted portfolio of <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporatebonds. Tracers typically conta<strong>in</strong> 30 to 35 <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bondswith an outstand<strong>in</strong>g issue size of $1 billion or more and have a diversifiedexposure to different <strong>in</strong>dustry sectors. Investors hold<strong>in</strong>g Tracers have theoption of either sell<strong>in</strong>g the custody receipts or redeem<strong>in</strong>g for the appropriatepro rata share of the underly<strong>in</strong>g securities on a weekly basis. Depend<strong>in</strong>gon <strong>in</strong>vestor demand for Tracers, Morgan Stanley has the option of creat<strong>in</strong>gadditional Tracer receipts on a weekly basis, which is done by deposit<strong>in</strong>gadditional securities with Bank of New York, the custodian. Tracers have as<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g fund structure and mature when the bond with the longest maturity<strong>in</strong> the portfolio expires.Tracers are issued by maturity (5, 10, and 30 years) and they rolldownthe yield curve. Tracers are quoted and traded on a spread basis tothe U.S. Treasury yield curve, and the transaction costs are <strong>in</strong> the range of3 to 5 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> yield. Morgan Stanley charges 4 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong>adm<strong>in</strong>istrative fee for manag<strong>in</strong>g the bond portfolio, which is subtractedfrom the coupons on the bonds as they are received. 11 The custodian paysthe coupon and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal received from the underly<strong>in</strong>g bonds to the<strong>in</strong>vestors 1 day after they are received. 12 Only qualified <strong>in</strong>stitutional<strong>in</strong>vestors can buy Tracers, because they are considered private securitiesdue to the trust structure.The portfolio composition of Tracers is designed to be static to improvetransparency. However, the underly<strong>in</strong>g portfolio composition can change asa result of the follow<strong>in</strong>g credit events and corporate actions:If any bond held <strong>in</strong> the portfolio is downgraded below <strong>in</strong>vestment gradeeither by Moody’s or Fitch, the adm<strong>in</strong>istrative agent auctions the bondand distributes the proceeds to <strong>in</strong>vestors.If the bond obligor defaults, the bond is auctioned and the proceeds aredistributed to the <strong>in</strong>vestors.In the event a corporate action arises for one of the bonds held <strong>in</strong> theportfolio, the adm<strong>in</strong>istrative agent auctions the bond if there is a lackof unanimity of op<strong>in</strong>ion among the <strong>in</strong>vestors.In each of these circumstances, the <strong>in</strong>vestor has the right to opt out of theauction and take physical delivery of the impacted security.Portfolio Composition and <strong>Risk</strong> CharacteristicsBecause any given Tracers series is primarily a portfolio of corporate bonds,analyz<strong>in</strong>g the risks of this structured credit portfolio can be performed us<strong>in</strong>g


232 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSthe methodology presented <strong>in</strong> the earlier chapters to quantify credit risk. Thisis particularly important for <strong>in</strong>vestors who may wish to analyze the relativevalue of buy<strong>in</strong>g, say, the 10-year Tracer versus buy<strong>in</strong>g a comparable-maturitycorporate bond that carries a similar risk profile. To address this question, Iconsider the series 2001-1 Tracer, whose portfolio composition is given <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 11.8. The series 2001-1 Tracer matures on 15 September 2011 andhad an average coupon of 7.252 percent as of 2 April 2003.EXHIBIT 11.8 Composition of 2001-1 Series Tracer as of 2 April 2003S. Issuer Coupon Nom<strong>in</strong>al Clean Yield ModifiedNo. Ticker Rat<strong>in</strong>g Maturity (%) (mn $) Price (%) Duration1 AA A2 01 Jun 11 6.500 54.50 111.52 4.778 6.2902 AOL Baa1 15 Apr 11 6.750 54.50 106.05 5.797 6.0293 AWE Baa2 01 Mar 11 7.875 54.50 111.89 5.966 5.9384 BAC Aa3 15 Jan 11 7.400 54.50 118.28 4.580 5.9965 BRITEL Baa1 15 Dec 10 8.375 54.50 121.83 4.931 5.7656 C Aa2 01 Oct 10 7.250 54.50 117.10 4.533 5.9147 COP A3 25 May 10 8.750 54.50 124.95 4.610 5.4018 DCX A3 18 Jan 11 7.750 54.50 113.09 5.648 5.8669 DD Aa3 15 Oct 09 6.875 54.50 117.04 3.895 5.22710 DT Baa3 15 Jun 10 8.000 54.50 117.70 5.037 5.50211 F A3 01 Feb 11 7.375 54.50 92.04 8.800 5.67012 FON Baa3 30 Jan 11 7.625 54.50 104.45 6.878 5.80513 FRTEL Baa3 01 Mar 11 7.750 54.50 119.61 4.747 6.06214 GE Aaa 19 Jan 10 7.375 54.50 117.03 4.442 5.39215 GM A2 15 Sep 11 6.875 54.50 97.91 7.209 6.27616 GS Aa3 15 Jan 11 6.875 54.50 112.88 4.866 6.04017 HSBC A2 15 May 11 6.750 54.50 110.48 5.153 6.17218 IADB Aaa 15 Jan 10 7.375 54.50 122.60 3.590 5.43819 JPM A2 01 Feb 11 6.750 54.50 110.88 5.049 6.08520 K Baa2 01 Apr 11 6.600 54.50 113.34 4.588 6.30821 MER Aa3 17 Feb 09 6.000 54.50 110.04 4.060 4.94722 NI Baa3 15 Nov 10 7.875 54.50 114.28 5.549 5.68923 ONE A1 01 Aug 10 7.875 54.50 120.86 4.500 5.68224 Q A1 22 Jan 11 6.125 54.50 112.87 4.174 6.22425 S Baa1 01 Feb 11 7.000 54.50 103.24 6.464 5.92826 SBC A1 15 Mar 11 6.250 54.50 110.87 4.601 6.31427 ULVR A1 01 Nov 10 7.125 54.50 117.91 4.327 5.85228 USB Aa3 01 Aug 11 6.375 54.50 112.64 4.534 6.49629 VIA A3 15 May 11 6.625 54.50 113.16 4.658 6.23930 VZ A2 01 Dec 10 7.250 54.50 116.04 4.728 5.88331 WB Aa3 18 Aug 10 7.800 54.50 121.16 4.407 5.74432 WMT Aa2 10 Aug 09 6.875 54.50 117.01 3.832 5.206


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 233Because Tracers can be seen simply as a portfolio of corporate bonds,we can try to quantify the risk of hold<strong>in</strong>g this corporate bond portfolioover a 1-year horizon us<strong>in</strong>g the technique presented <strong>in</strong> Chapter 6. To simplifymatters, I assume the asset return correlation between every obligor pairto be 30 percent when comput<strong>in</strong>g various portfolio credit risk quantitiesof <strong>in</strong>terest under the migration mode. In perform<strong>in</strong>g the simulations, thejo<strong>in</strong>t distribution of asset returns was assumed to be mult<strong>in</strong>ormal withmean recovery rate of 47 percent across all bonds. To exam<strong>in</strong>e the impacton portfolio credit risk due to an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> asset return correlationbetween obligors, a second simulation run was performed with an assetreturn correlation of 45 percent across obligor pairs. The weighted averagerat<strong>in</strong>g factor for this portfolio based on current market values was alsocomputed us<strong>in</strong>g Moody’s rat<strong>in</strong>g factors given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 11.6. The aggregateportfolio risk characteristics of the series 2001-1 Tracer are shown <strong>in</strong>Exhibit 11.9.Moody’s rated the series 2001-1 Tracer Baa1 as of April 2003. Giventhis <strong>in</strong>formation, an <strong>in</strong>vestor might be confronted with the follow<strong>in</strong>g question:Is the <strong>in</strong>vestment risk <strong>in</strong> Tracers the same as the risk of hold<strong>in</strong>g a Baa1-rated corporate bond? I address this important question <strong>in</strong> the next section.Implied <strong>Credit</strong> Rat<strong>in</strong>gDriven by the desire to reduce downside risk, <strong>in</strong>vestors hold a portfoliorather than a s<strong>in</strong>gle security. Hold<strong>in</strong>g a diversified portfolio protects<strong>in</strong>vestors from large losses that may otherwise occur when only a s<strong>in</strong>glef<strong>in</strong>ancial security is held. Given this observation, it is more likely that an<strong>in</strong>vestor would prefer to buy a Tracer with a Baa1 rat<strong>in</strong>g than a Baa1-ratedbond hav<strong>in</strong>g a similar duration risk and yield. This br<strong>in</strong>gs up the follow<strong>in</strong>gEXHIBIT 11.9<strong>Risk</strong> Characteristics of a Tracer PortfolioAsset ReturnAsset ReturnDescription Correlation 30 Percent Correlation 45 PercentAverage yield (%) 4.97 4.97Modified duration 5.85 5.85Moody’s WARF 181 181Expected loss (bp) 32.1 32.1Unexpected loss (bp) 90.3 113.0CrVaR at 90 percentconfidence (bp) 111.6 113.3ESR at 90 percentconfidence (bp) 229.4 272.1


234 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSquestion: How do rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies rate a portfolio of corporate bonds? Some<strong>in</strong>sight <strong>in</strong>to how rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies assess the risk of a portfolio of corporatebonds can be obta<strong>in</strong>ed on the basis of the rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies methodology forCDOs presented earlier. Both Moody’s and Fitch, for <strong>in</strong>stance, use theexpected loss of the portfolio as an <strong>in</strong>put parameter to determ<strong>in</strong>e an appropriatecredit rat<strong>in</strong>g.This approach can be extended to Tracers; the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g forthe underly<strong>in</strong>g portfolio of bonds <strong>in</strong> a Tracer can be derived us<strong>in</strong>g thefollow<strong>in</strong>g simple rule:First, compute the expected loss of the corporate bond portfolio.In the next step, compute the set of expected losses for a bond hav<strong>in</strong>gthe same duration and yield as the portfolio, but with different creditrat<strong>in</strong>gs.F<strong>in</strong>ally, identify the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g under which the expected loss for thebond is approximately equal to the corporate bond portfolio’s expectedloss.At first glance, this procedure may appear rather naive for comput<strong>in</strong>g acorporate bond portfolio’s credit rat<strong>in</strong>g. Even for a casual observer it willbe evident that no risk measure is be<strong>in</strong>g used to derive the implied creditrat<strong>in</strong>g of the portfolio. To <strong>in</strong>vestigate whether this simple procedure willlead to a Baa1 rat<strong>in</strong>g for the series 2001-1 Tracer as assigned by Moody’s,consider a bond with the follow<strong>in</strong>g characteristics as of trade date 2 April2003: a 7.252 percent annual coupon, matur<strong>in</strong>g on 20 September 2010,and trad<strong>in</strong>g at a clean price of $114.10. Such a bond will have an identicalyield, modified duration, and convexity as the bond portfolio that constitutesthe series 2001-1 Tracer. The expected and unexpected losses of thisbond under the migration mode assum<strong>in</strong>g different credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs for thebond are given <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 11.10. In deriv<strong>in</strong>g the expected and unexpectedloss, a recovery rate of 47 percent was assumed.Compar<strong>in</strong>g Exhibits 11.9 and 11.10, one see <strong>in</strong>fer that on the basis ofthe expected loss <strong>in</strong>formation, the series 2001-1 Tracer will be assigned aBaa1 rat<strong>in</strong>g. As mentioned earlier, this also happens to be the rat<strong>in</strong>gassigned by Moody’s to this structured portfolio. Note that we were able toEXHIBIT 11.10<strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> Measures for a <strong>Bond</strong> with Same Duration as a TracerDescription A1 Rated A2 Rated A3 Rated Baa1 RatedExpected loss (bp) 22.5 24.4 38.7 32.9Unexpected loss (bp) 196.4 224.3 267.0 301.9ESR at 90 percent confidence (bp) 272.6 308.0 463.7 508.1


Structured <strong>Credit</strong> Products 235arrive at Moody’s credit rat<strong>in</strong>g for this portfolio without hav<strong>in</strong>g to modelthe obligor asset return correlations. A similar conclusion holds for theimplied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of the portfolio if the WARF score is exam<strong>in</strong>ed. Forexample, WARF for the portfolio is 181, and this is higher than the thresholdvalue of 180 for an A3-rated bond. This also leads to the conclusionthat the bond portfolio has a Baa1 rat<strong>in</strong>g.Unfortunately, both WARF as well as the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of theportfolio established on the basis of expected loss <strong>in</strong>formation lead toimproper <strong>in</strong>terpretation of the actual risk associated with the underly<strong>in</strong>gportfolio. The credit risk fac<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>vestor hold<strong>in</strong>g a s<strong>in</strong>gle bond ratedBaa1 is fundamentally different from the credit risk faced by an <strong>in</strong>vestorhold<strong>in</strong>g a Baa1-rated series 2001-1 Tracer even if they both have identicalmarket risks. This is evident from exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the unexpected loss of thereplicat<strong>in</strong>g bond shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 11.10 under different credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs. Infact, the unexpected loss of the Tracer assum<strong>in</strong>g 45 percent asset return correlationbetween obligor pairs is only half of that of an A2-rated bond.Hav<strong>in</strong>g established that the true risks are not reflected <strong>in</strong> the credit rat<strong>in</strong>gassigned by rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies <strong>in</strong> the portfolio context, one can explorealternative methods of arriv<strong>in</strong>g at an implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g for a portfoliothat better reflect the risks. In arriv<strong>in</strong>g at this implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g, assumethat the <strong>in</strong>vestor is <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> compar<strong>in</strong>g the potential downside risksbetween the series 2001-1 Tracer and a bond hav<strong>in</strong>g the same market riskprofile. One measure that can be used to quantify this downside risk is theexpected shortfall risk <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> Chapter 7. 13 The ESRs at 90 percentlevel of confidence for the replicat<strong>in</strong>g bond are shown <strong>in</strong> Exhibit 11.10assum<strong>in</strong>g different credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs for the bond. Under the assumption thatthe bond has an A1 rat<strong>in</strong>g, the ESR at 90 percent level of confidence is equalto 272.6 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts. This value is close to ESR at 90 percent confidencelevel for the series 2001-1 Tracer when the asset return correlation betweenobligors is assumed to be 45 percent.Clearly, an <strong>in</strong>vestor worried about the downside risk will consider buy<strong>in</strong>gthe series 2001-1 Tracer as be<strong>in</strong>g equivalent to buy<strong>in</strong>g a bond rated A1with the same market risk characteristics. Because the numerical resultssuggest that the 1-year expected loss of an A1-rated bond is 10 basis po<strong>in</strong>tslower than that for the Tracer, the <strong>in</strong>vestor would break even if the yield ofthe series 2001-1 Tracer is 10 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts more than an A1-rated bond ofcomparable maturity. F<strong>in</strong>ally, it is important to note that the use of a downsiderisk measure as opposed to expected loss to <strong>in</strong>fer the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of aportfolio leads to a three-notch rat<strong>in</strong>g difference for the example consideredhere. Such a large difference <strong>in</strong> the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of a structuredcredit product suggests that further research is needed to resolve thesedifferences and to f<strong>in</strong>d the best approach to be used for rat<strong>in</strong>g structuredcredit products.


236 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSQUESTIONS1. What are the similarities and differences between CDOs and assetbackedsecurities?2. What factors make a CDO attractive from an <strong>in</strong>vestor’s perspective?3. What is subord<strong>in</strong>ation and how does it provide credit enhancement tosenior CDO tranches?4. Expla<strong>in</strong> what “par-build<strong>in</strong>g” trades mean and how this practice canlead to worsen<strong>in</strong>g of collateral quality.5. What is diversity score and what purpose does it serve?6. What are the advantages and disadvantages of us<strong>in</strong>g market value testsfor cash flow CDOs?7. You are asked to provide a list of relative merits between buy<strong>in</strong>g anA1-rated cash flow CBO and an A1-rated Tracer, both matur<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> 3 years, to your management. What are the important po<strong>in</strong>tsyou will list?


Solutions to End-of-ChapterQuestionsCHAPTER 21. This experiment leads to a random variable that has a b<strong>in</strong>omial distribution.The random variable X of a b<strong>in</strong>omial distribution counts thenumber of successes <strong>in</strong> n trials. If p is the probability of an event occurr<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> a given trial, the probability of this event occurr<strong>in</strong>g r times <strong>in</strong> ntrials is given byP(X r) n!r!(n r)! pr (1 p) nrThe probability that the face 6 will show up at least two times is 1m<strong>in</strong>us the probability that the face 6 shows up once <strong>in</strong> 10 trials. Theseare given, respectively, byP(X 2) 1 P(X 1) 1 10191 A 1 6B 1 A 5 6B 9 0.6770andP(X 2) 10!2! 8! A1 6B 2 A 5 6B 8 0.29072. The mean and variance of the random variable are given, respectively,byand 2 a6i1 ani1x i p(x i ) a6(x i ) 2 p(x i ) a6i1i1i 1 6 3.5(i 3.5) 2 1 6 2.917237


238 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS3. The 10th percentile of the distribution corresponds to the 0.1 quantile.If x p is the 0.1 quantile of a normal distribution, x p solves the follow<strong>in</strong>gequation:x1 p(x )2exp ¢ ≤ dx 0.122 2 2qFor 0.5 and 1.2, this gives x p 1.03784. For a beta distribution, the mean and variance are given, respectively,byand 2 ( ) 2 (1)For 1.4 and 1.58, we have 0.47 and 0.25.If f(x) denotes the density function of a beta distribution, the probabilitythat the recovery rate lies between 20 and 80 percent of parvalue dur<strong>in</strong>g simulations is given by0.80.20.8f(x)dx q0.2f(x)dx f(x)dx 0.7095q5. The mean and volatility of the recovery rate process are given, respectively,byand a b2 b a2120.2 0.820.8 0.2212 0.5 0.1736. Take, for example, 3 3 matrices and show this is true. The generalcase follows easily. Let the matrices A and B be given bya 11 a 12 a 13b 11 b 12 b 13A £ a 21 a 22 a 23 § and B £ b 21 b 22 b 23 §a 31 a 32 a 33 b 31 b 32 b 33


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 239If C denotes the product A B, then the first row of this matrix is givenbyc 11 a 11 b 11 a 12 b 21 a 13 b 31c 12 a 11 b 12 a 12 b 22 a 13 b 32c 13 a 11 b 13 a 12 b 23 a 13 b 33For any Markov matrix, the sum of the row elements must add to one.To see if this is true, check the follow<strong>in</strong>g identity:c 11 c 12 c 13 a 11 (b 11 b 12 b 13 ) a 12 (b 21 b 22 b 23 ) a 13 (b 31 b 32 b 33 ) a 11 a 12 a 13 1This follows from the fact that A and B are Markov matrices. Similarly,one can show that the other rows of the matrix C also add up to one,and hence, the result.7. Apply<strong>in</strong>g a result from l<strong>in</strong>ear algebra, one can represent any matrix A<strong>in</strong> terms of its eigenvector decomposition given byA SS 1where S is the matrix formed us<strong>in</strong>g eigenvectors of A and is a diagonalmatrix conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g eigenvalues of A. Us<strong>in</strong>g this relation, one hasA 2 SS 1 SS 1 S 2 S 1Note that the eigenvalues of the matrix A 2 are the diagonal elements ofthe matrix 2 . The last exercise showed that if A is Markov, then A 2 isalso Markov. Denote the Markov matrix A 2 P and let the eigenvaluesof P be given by the diagonal matrix P 2 . It follows then thatP 1/2 SS 1 S P1/2S 1 ABecause A is by construction a Markov matrix, so is P 1/2 , us<strong>in</strong>g theeigenvalue decomposition. In the general case, it follows that for any<strong>in</strong>teger value n, the decompositionP 1/n S P1/nS1


240 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSis a Markov matrix.8.0.9555 0.0380 0.0065P 1/12 £ 0.0127 0.9681 0.0192 §0 0 10.7670 0.1879 0.0451P 1/2 £ 0.0626 0.8296 0.1078 §0 0 19. The eigenvalues are 1 5.8284, 2 2.0, and 3 0.1716. Theeigenvectors are0.382700.9239x 1 £ 0.9239 § , x 2 £ 0 § , x 3 £ 0.3827 §010The Cholesky decomposition is A LL T , where1 0 0L £ 2 1 0 §0 0 1.414210. The first two pr<strong>in</strong>cipal components expla<strong>in</strong> a variance ofl 1 l 2 7.8284 97.85 percentl 1 l 2 l 3 811. The normalized direction vectors are / 1 [0.7071 0 0.7071] Tand / Thus 2 1 / T 1 A/ 1 1.5, 2 2 / T 2 [1 0 0] T .2 A/ 2 1.0,0.5773The variance expla<strong>in</strong>ed by these factors is 2 1 2 2 (1 ) 24.03 percentl 1 l 2 l 3CHAPTER 31. Different forms of bond collateralization used for securitization <strong>in</strong>cludethe follow<strong>in</strong>g:a. Mortgage bonds backed by real estate or other physical property.


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 241b. Collateral trust bonds secured by f<strong>in</strong>ancial assets such as stocks,bonds, and other securities, which are deposited with a trustee.c. Equipment trust certificates, which are secured by ownership of specificequipment, usually capital <strong>in</strong> nature, with the title to this equipmentheld by a trustee.d. Asset-backed securities, which are secured by home-equity loans,credit card receivables, and auto loans.2. Major <strong>in</strong>vestment risks that face corporate bond <strong>in</strong>vestors can be classifiedunder the follow<strong>in</strong>g categories:a. <strong>Credit</strong> risk, which arises from either the bond obligor becom<strong>in</strong>gbankrupt or the obligor be<strong>in</strong>g downgraded to lower credit quality.b. Market risk, which results from an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the general level of<strong>in</strong>terest rates.c. Liquidity risk, which arises from the lack of marketability of a bond.d. Economic risk, which arises from a general slowdown of the globaleconomy, which <strong>in</strong> turn leads to lower corporate profits and thereforelower debt-repay<strong>in</strong>g capacity of many corporate borrowers.3. <strong>Corporate</strong> bond trad<strong>in</strong>g is done through a broker/dealer market. <strong>Bond</strong>snot sold back to <strong>in</strong>vestors and held <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ventory for longer time periods<strong>in</strong>cur capital charges. <strong>Bond</strong> dealers also face the risk of the bond obligorbe<strong>in</strong>g downgraded, which results <strong>in</strong> a lower trade price for the bond.Higher bid–ask spreads charged to compensate for these risks force<strong>in</strong>vestors to trade corporate bonds <strong>in</strong>frequently. This is turn reducesturnover <strong>in</strong> corporates, and, as a consequence, <strong>in</strong>creases the risk ofhold<strong>in</strong>g bonds <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ventory by dealers longer than they would normallywish. The sum total of these effects contributes to higher trad<strong>in</strong>g costsfor corporate bonds.4. Trad<strong>in</strong>g cost per year is given by 2.5 5 1.25 15.625 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts.5. Dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of economic crisis, corporate bonds offer economicenterprises an alternative fund<strong>in</strong>g source when banks cut down onlend<strong>in</strong>g. This diversity of fund<strong>in</strong>g sources provides <strong>in</strong>surance aga<strong>in</strong>st af<strong>in</strong>ancial problem turn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to economywide distress. Furthermore,because fund<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the capital markets competes with bank lend<strong>in</strong>g,borrow<strong>in</strong>g costs for corporates are lower dur<strong>in</strong>g normal times. <strong>Corporate</strong>bonds also provide <strong>in</strong>vestors with alternative <strong>in</strong>vestment opportunities.F<strong>in</strong>ally, well-developed corporate bond markets br<strong>in</strong>g marketdiscipl<strong>in</strong>e and reduce the scope for misdirected credit allocations.6. Carry<strong>in</strong>g out a historical performance analysis of various asset classescan help identify relationships between them that are otherwise notevident. Experience suggests that historical performance analysis isvery useful for predict<strong>in</strong>g future volatility of returns of the asset classand reasonably useful for predict<strong>in</strong>g the correlation between thereturns of different asset classes. Furthermore, to evaluate the potential


242 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSrisks associated with <strong>in</strong>vestment decisions, an analysis of historical performanceis required.7. Hold<strong>in</strong>g larger than necessary level of foreign currency reserves <strong>in</strong>curscosts <strong>in</strong> real resources. Reserve managers are faced with the challenge ofreduc<strong>in</strong>g these costs by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g return on reserves. However, given thepublic scrut<strong>in</strong>y of the <strong>in</strong>vestment returns, losses aris<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>in</strong>vestmentdecisions need to be kept to a m<strong>in</strong>imum. This requires <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong>high-grade, low-volatility assets, which, however, deliver low returns. Themajor challenge faced by reserve managers is to meet the objective of generat<strong>in</strong>ghigher returns without tak<strong>in</strong>g much credit or <strong>in</strong>terest rate risk.8. Given the yield pickup over comparable-maturity U.S. Treasury securities,corporate bonds offer the opportunity to generate higher returnsthan <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> Treasury securities. Furthermore, <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>corporate bonds lowers the volatility of returns relative to an <strong>in</strong>vestment<strong>in</strong> Treasuries with similar duration. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the correlation of corporatebond returns with Treasury and other high-grade credits be<strong>in</strong>gless than one will lead to some diversification benefit. This will have theeffect of reduc<strong>in</strong>g the volatility of returns on the overall reserves if thereis <strong>in</strong>creased exposure to corporates <strong>in</strong> the reserves portfolio.9. Under the new account<strong>in</strong>g rules, the pension fund assets have to bemarked to market and the present value of pension liabilities has to becomputed by discount<strong>in</strong>g future liabilities by the long-term yield of corporatebonds. Dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of economic recession, these rules will havethe effect of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the present value of liabilities due to a fall <strong>in</strong> longtermyields while at the same time produc<strong>in</strong>g lower valuations for theassets due to the fall<strong>in</strong>g equities market. The impact of these two will bequite serious for those pension funds that have greater exposure to equities,because the coverage ratio (pension assets divided by pension liabilities)will fall. In a def<strong>in</strong>ed benefit scheme, this will force corporations to<strong>in</strong>crease pension contributions to keep the coverage ratio above themandatory m<strong>in</strong>imum level. To m<strong>in</strong>imize this risk, pension sponsors mayhave a tendency to <strong>in</strong>clude a greater proportion of corporate bonds toserve as a better hedg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>strument under the new account<strong>in</strong>g rules.10. In a def<strong>in</strong>ed benefit pension scheme, the pension sponsor has to makeadditional pension contributions if pension assets do not generate sufficientreturns to cover actuarial liabilities. This risk is referred to as surplusrisk, which is the risk that the assets will fall short of liabilities. Toreduce surplus risk, plan sponsors have to ensure that the sensitivity tomodeled risk factors across assets and liabilities are broadly matched.For example, liabilities are higher if the long-term yields on corporatebonds decl<strong>in</strong>e. To ensure that pension assets are also higher under thisscenario, greater exposure to corporate bonds is required <strong>in</strong> the pensionassets. The amount of surplus risk, <strong>in</strong> practice, has to be balanced


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 243aga<strong>in</strong>st the expected return on the pension assets, which has to be <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>ewith the expected growth rate of real earn<strong>in</strong>gs. This is required to ensurethat the pension contribution rate for the plan sponsor is not too high.CHAPTER 41. The yield to maturity is 4.674 percent, the modified duration is 3.748,the convexity is 16.85, and the approximate price change is $0.955.2. The yield to maturity is 4.412 percent, the modified duration is 5.623,and the convexity is 44.10. The bond manager’s view is that the yieldswill decrease and the yield curve will flatten.3. The motivation for do<strong>in</strong>g pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysis of the yieldcurve is to understand the correlation structure between yields acrossdifferent maturities. Because yields across maturities are correlated,pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysis helps to reduce the number of <strong>in</strong>dependentfactors required to expla<strong>in</strong> the yield curve dynamics.4. Let / s denote the normalized shift vector and the covariancematrix of yield changes. The second factor / t can be determ<strong>in</strong>ed bysolv<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g optimization problem: Maximize subject tothe constra<strong>in</strong>tsand / T/ Tt / s ©/ / Tt ©/ tt 0t 1.5. The track<strong>in</strong>g error of a portfolio is the annualized standard deviationof the weekly or daily return differences between the portfolio and thebenchmark. This def<strong>in</strong>ition leads to an ex post measure of track<strong>in</strong>gerror. A monthly track<strong>in</strong>g error of 25 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts corresponds to25212 86.6 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts annualized track<strong>in</strong>g error.6. The market value of the portfolio is M p $3,646,265; the marketvalue after the yield curve shift is M s p $3,666,849; and the marketvalue after the yield curve twist is M t p $3.650,741. Then,CHAPTER 5shift sensitivity M p s M pM ptwist sensitivity M p t M pM p 56.45 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts 12.27 basis po<strong>in</strong>ts1. Given A 0 $12, F $10, 5 percent, and A 10 percent, use theequationD ln(A 0F) ( 0.5 A 2 )T A 2T


244 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSSubstitut<strong>in</strong>g the forego<strong>in</strong>g values gives D 2.273. The 1-year defaultprobability is given by PD N(D), orDPD 1 exp(0.5x 2 )dx 0.011522q2. Many of the assumptions made under Merton’s approach to determ<strong>in</strong>ethe default probability of a firm are violated <strong>in</strong> practice. These <strong>in</strong>cludethe follow<strong>in</strong>g: (a) firms seldom issue zero-coupon debt and there areusually multiple liabilities, (b) firms <strong>in</strong> distress may be able to draw onl<strong>in</strong>es of credit that will result <strong>in</strong> a change <strong>in</strong> the liabilities, and (c) assetreturns of firms may deviate from a normal distribution. As a result,apply<strong>in</strong>g Merton’s method <strong>in</strong> practice to determ<strong>in</strong>e the default probabilityof a firm is usually difficult.The KMV approach resolves these difficulties as follows: (a) Thedefault po<strong>in</strong>t that triggers bankruptcy is assumed to be the sum of theshort-term and one half of the long-term liabilities and (b) the distance todefault variable is mapped to a historical default statistics database toestimate the probability of default.3. The structural approach leads to default probability estimates that aremore responsive to current economic environment. The empiricalapproach, on the other hand, leads to default probability estimates thatreflect long-term averages. Although <strong>in</strong>creased responsiveness tochanges <strong>in</strong> economic conditions on the firm’s default probability hasmany advantages, this feature may be undesirable if the estimates areused for the purpose of economic capital allocation. Another potentialdrawback of the structural approach followed by KMV is that defaultprobability predictions for regulated banks tend to be higher than whathistorical data would suggest. This is primarily because the historicaldefault database conta<strong>in</strong>s ma<strong>in</strong>ly corporates and not banks.4. Recovery rates on defaulted bonds are estimated based on the trad<strong>in</strong>gprice of the bond <strong>in</strong> the secondary market approximately 1 month afterthe default event. The factors that <strong>in</strong>fluence recovery rates <strong>in</strong>clude theseniority of the bond issue, the <strong>in</strong>dustrial sector to which the bondissuer belongs, the state of the economy, and the credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of theissuer 1 year prior to default.5. Rat<strong>in</strong>g outlooks are forward-look<strong>in</strong>g assessment of the creditworth<strong>in</strong>essof issuers over the medium term published by rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies. Rat<strong>in</strong>goutlooks assess the potential direction of an issuer’s rat<strong>in</strong>g changeover the next 6 months to 2 years. Changes <strong>in</strong> rat<strong>in</strong>g outlooks <strong>in</strong>fluencebond prices, and sometimes significant price changes may occur aftersuch changes <strong>in</strong> outlook are published. Price changes occur because a


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 245change <strong>in</strong> rat<strong>in</strong>g outlook is considered by market participants as a signal<strong>in</strong>gevent used by rat<strong>in</strong>g agencies before eventually upgrad<strong>in</strong>g ordowngrad<strong>in</strong>g an issuer’s credit rat<strong>in</strong>g.6. Here, P dirty $103.50, PD 0.002, RR 0.47, RR 0.25, NE $10million, and LD 1.035 0.47 0.565. Thus EL PD LD $11,3002UL NE 2PD RR LD 2 PD(1 PD) $276,0757. Empirical evidence <strong>in</strong>dicates that recovery rates are negatively correlatedwith default rates. Reduced-form models do not take this relationship<strong>in</strong>to account. Reduced-form models assume that recovery rate anddefault rate processes are <strong>in</strong>dependent.8. Yields on corporate bonds vary significantly across issuers. These yielddifferences for a given maturity can be significant even among issuershav<strong>in</strong>g identical credit rat<strong>in</strong>g and belong<strong>in</strong>g to the same <strong>in</strong>dustrial sector.As a result, yield curves that are constructed for a specified creditrat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>troduce large pric<strong>in</strong>g errors if bonds are priced off these yieldcurves. Because bonds have to be repriced under rat<strong>in</strong>g change scenarios,comput<strong>in</strong>g mean<strong>in</strong>gful price changes under rat<strong>in</strong>g changes acrossall bonds would be practically impossible.Although pric<strong>in</strong>g bonds off generic yield curves runs <strong>in</strong>to difficulties,generic yield curves for different credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs can still be constructed andused <strong>in</strong> a mean<strong>in</strong>gful way if these yield curves are used primarily tocompute yield spreads across different maturities and credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs. Thisgives a richer description of yield spreads, which are differentiated bymaturity and credit rat<strong>in</strong>g. Moreover, this also reflects the current yieldspreads when estimat<strong>in</strong>g credit risk under the migration mode rather thanthe static values used for illustration purposes <strong>in</strong> this book. Yield spreadsderived us<strong>in</strong>g such curves could be used <strong>in</strong> conjunction with the durationand the convexity of the bond to compute the price changes.9.18EL NE a p ik ¢P ikk1 10,000,000 0.001892 $18,9202UL NE PD B RR 10,000,000 20.002 0.25 2 3.768 10 4 0.001892 2 $223,208.5 a18k1182p ik ¢P 2 ik ¢ a p ik ¢P ik ≤k1


246 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSCHAPTER 61. Aggregation of portfolio credit risk requires estimat<strong>in</strong>g the standarddeviation of loss (unexpected loss) of the securities held <strong>in</strong> the portfolioand the correlation between security losses. Aggregation of marketrisk requires estimat<strong>in</strong>g the standard deviation of returns of the securitiesheld <strong>in</strong> the portfolio and the correlation between security returns.In this respect, aggregation of credit risk and market risk are quite similar<strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple. The major difference, however, is that the distributionof security losses result<strong>in</strong>g from credit events is highly skewed, whereasthe distribution of security returns driven by market-related events isapproximately normal. The knowledge of the standard deviation of anormally distributed random variable is sufficient to derive tail risk statistics.Deriv<strong>in</strong>g tail risk measures for credit risk requires perform<strong>in</strong>g aMonte Carlo simulation. The other difference between market andcredit risk perta<strong>in</strong>s to the ease with which data required to computethese measures can be obta<strong>in</strong>ed. For market risk, one only needs dailyor weekly time series of security returns, which is observed <strong>in</strong> the market.Variables that are required to aggregate credit risk are usually notobserved and therefore require mak<strong>in</strong>g assumptions.2. As the term suggests, asset return correlation between two obligors isthe correlation between asset returns of the obligors. Default correlationis the correlation between the default <strong>in</strong>dicators for the twoobligors, typically over a 1-year time horizon. Loss correlation is thecorrelation between the credit losses of the two obligors, where thecredit losses are usually measured over a 1-year time horizon. Defaultcorrelation is typically an order of magnitude less than asset correlation.Loss correlation magnitude depends on whether the credit riskis to be aggregated under the default mode or the migration mode.Under the migration mode, the credit loss result<strong>in</strong>g from rat<strong>in</strong>gchanges is also <strong>in</strong>cluded and hence will be higher than under thedefault mode.3. The assessment of the risk of f<strong>in</strong>ancial securities is based on models thatcapture the price dynamics of these securities. Model risk refers to therisk that such models may not describe the price dynamics of the f<strong>in</strong>ancialsecurities accurately. This could arise, for <strong>in</strong>stance, when simplify<strong>in</strong>gassumptions are made to keep the model complexity manageable.The model risk associated with quantification of credit risk is quitehigh. This is ma<strong>in</strong>ly due to the many simplify<strong>in</strong>g assumptions that haveto be made to keep the model tractable. Furthermore, many variablesthat are used for model<strong>in</strong>g credit risk are not directly observable. Thistends to <strong>in</strong>crease model risk further by <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g an additional layerof uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty.


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 2474. Under the assumption that recovery rates are positively correlated,the expected value of the jo<strong>in</strong>t losses is higher. This results <strong>in</strong> higherloss correlation between the two obligors. One can verify this fromthe follow<strong>in</strong>g relation for the jo<strong>in</strong>t expected value of two randomvariables:E(XY) E(X)E(Y) XY X YClearly, E(XY) is higher if the random variables are positively correlated.5. The jo<strong>in</strong>t default probability <strong>in</strong> this case is 5.7033 10 6 . The expectedloss of the portfolio is $1,009.6. The unexpected loss us<strong>in</strong>g the defaultcorrelation is $26,135.5. The unexpected loss us<strong>in</strong>g the loss correlationis $6,123.8.6. The leverage ratio of a firm is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the ratio between the facevalue of outstand<strong>in</strong>g debt and the asset value of the firm. If w i denotesthe leverage ratio of the ith firm, the asset return of the ith firm can beapproximated as follows:r i A (1 w i ) r S i w i r FiiiHere, r S is the equity return of the firm and r F is the return on a riskfreebond issued by the firm. This equation allows one to approximatethe asset return covariance between two firms i and k us<strong>in</strong>g the equityreturn covariance between these firms as follows:covAr A i ,r A k B (1 w i ) (1 w k ) covAr s i ,r S k B w i w k covAr F i ,r F k BIf the leverage ratio is high, the last term <strong>in</strong> the above equation willdom<strong>in</strong>ate. Because the correlation between two risk-free bonds will bemuch higher than the equity return correlation between two firms, theasset return correlation between two firms with high leverage ratio willbe much higher than the equity return correlation between the firms.7. Because asset returns are not observable, comput<strong>in</strong>g the asset returncorrelation between obligors requires <strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>g this value us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>directapproaches. Factor models render the task of estimat<strong>in</strong>g the assetreturn correlation between obligors easy by identify<strong>in</strong>g common factorsto which the bus<strong>in</strong>ess risks of two companies are exposed. Moreover, ifa company’s bus<strong>in</strong>ess changes as a result of mergers and acquisitions,the future prospects of the company change. This leads to a change <strong>in</strong>the asset return correlation aga<strong>in</strong>st other companies. Factor modelscapture these changes by recogniz<strong>in</strong>g the changes <strong>in</strong> the sensitivities tocommon factors for the company.


248 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS8. The z-threshold values will be different if the true mean and standarddeviation of asset returns are used <strong>in</strong> the calculations. One can showus<strong>in</strong>g change of variables that if z i is the z-threshold under the truemean and standard deviation of the asset returns, then the new thresholdwill be given byw i (z i )9. The loss correlation is 0.03598, EL P $4,740, and UL P $31,210.CHAPTER 71. The convergence of a Monte Carlo simulation can be speeded up by us<strong>in</strong>gquasi-random sequences or by perform<strong>in</strong>g importance sampl<strong>in</strong>g. Quasirandomsequences are sequences of n-tuples that fill n-dimensionalspace more uniformly than uncorrelated po<strong>in</strong>ts generated by pseudorandomsequences. Hence, fewer simulations are required to get thesame convergence efficiency with quasi-random sequences than withpseudo-random sequences. Importance sampl<strong>in</strong>g helps to speed upthe simulations by generat<strong>in</strong>g random numbers around the region of<strong>in</strong>terest. This is useful when one is <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> comput<strong>in</strong>g tail riskmeasures.2. The loss distribution result<strong>in</strong>g from credit risk is a skewed distributionwith a long, fat tail. Given the first two moments of this distribution, itis not possible to ga<strong>in</strong> much <strong>in</strong>sight <strong>in</strong>to the credit losses around the tailof the distribution. For a fat-tailed distribution, a measure of the tailrisk is critical for exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the scope for large losses to occur. Theonly way to measure this risk is by perform<strong>in</strong>g a Monte Carlo simulationto generate the credit loss distribution.3. The ma<strong>in</strong> computational steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> simulat<strong>in</strong>g the credit loss distributionare the follow<strong>in</strong>g:a. Simulate correlated random numbers that model the jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionof asset returns of the obligors <strong>in</strong> the portfoliob. Infer the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g of each obligor based on simulatedasset returnsc. Compute the potential loss <strong>in</strong> value based on the implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g,and <strong>in</strong> those cases where the asset return value signals an obligordefault, compute a random loss on default value by sampl<strong>in</strong>gfrom a beta distribution function.Repeat<strong>in</strong>g the above simulation runs many number of times allows oneto compute the distribution of credit losses.


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 2494. The expected and unexpected losses are the same <strong>in</strong> both cases. This isbecause the expected and the unexpected loss of the portfolio aredependent only on the mean and the standard deviation of the recoveryrates. Evidence for this follows from the analytical expressions derivedfor expected and unexpected loss where the knowledge of the recoveryrate distribution was not required to derive these expressions.5. The only modification required <strong>in</strong> the Monte Carlo simulations is todraw correlated recovery rate vectors dur<strong>in</strong>g the simulation runs. This,of course, requires mak<strong>in</strong>g an assumption on the appropriate jo<strong>in</strong>t distributionfor the recovery rate variables.6. For a normal distribution, knowledge of the mean and the standarddeviation of the distribution allows one to completely characterize theshape of the distribution. Hence, any tail statistic of <strong>in</strong>terest can bederived know<strong>in</strong>g the mean and the standard deviation of the distribution.This suggests that if the distribution of credit losses happened tobe normally distributed, perform<strong>in</strong>g a Monte Carlo simulation forcomput<strong>in</strong>g tail risk measures will be not necessary if the expected andthe unexpected loss of the distribution are given.7. Yes, one should be will<strong>in</strong>g to play the game. Because the expected payoffis equal to the <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>vestment to play the game, this is a fair game.8. Because the expected payoff is still equal to the <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>vestment, it isstill a fair game. However, because there are eight balls with zero payoff,there is 8 percent chance of loos<strong>in</strong>g $5 and 13 percent chance thatthe loss will be $4 or more. This <strong>in</strong>creases the downside risk considerably.If, as an <strong>in</strong>vestor, one focuses on the downside risk, one shouldnot be will<strong>in</strong>g to play this game.9. The various statistical parameters of <strong>in</strong>terest for Question 7 are mean $5, $1.378, VaR(90%) $2, and ESR(90%) $3. The statisticalparameters of <strong>in</strong>terest for Question 8 are mean $5, $1.851,VaR(90%) $3.333, and ESR(90%) $4.667.CHAPTER 81. F<strong>in</strong>ancial time series data exhibit a property known as tail dependence.Under tail dependence, there is greater degree of co-movement ofreturns across firms dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of large market moves compared tothose observed dur<strong>in</strong>g normal market conditions. Because multivariatenormal distributions do not exhibit tail dependence, model<strong>in</strong>g the jo<strong>in</strong>tdistribution of asset returns as multivariate normal will fail to modelherd<strong>in</strong>g and contagion behavior <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets, which representlarge correlated market moves.


250 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOS2. The multivariate t distribution exhibits tail dependence and hence willbe able to capture correlated extreme market moves. Moreover, Student’st distribution <strong>in</strong>herits the correlation matrix of normal distributions.Hence, the correlation matrix for multivariate t distribution is easy tocalibrate. F<strong>in</strong>ally, it is quite easy to generate sequences of multivariatet-distributed random variables, which makes the task of perform<strong>in</strong>gnumerical simulations to evaluate credit risk fairly simple.3. As the number of degrees of freedom <strong>in</strong> the multivariate t distributionis reduced, the degree of tail dependence <strong>in</strong>creases. This has the implicationthat the portfolio credit loss distribution will have fat tails andhence tail risk measures will <strong>in</strong>crease significantly.4. (a) 2.576; (b) 3.355.5. (a) $26,803; (b) $26,680.6. The follow<strong>in</strong>g are the steps <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g an n-dimensionalsequence of multivariate t-distributed random variables with degreesof freedom:Step 1. Compute the Cholesky factor L of the matrix C, where C is then n asset return correlation matrix.Step 2. Simulate n <strong>in</strong>dependent standard normal random variates z 1 ,z 2 ,...,z n and set u Lz.Step 3. Simulate a random variate from a chi-square distributionwith degrees of freedom that is <strong>in</strong>dependent of the normal randomvariates and set s 1/1.Step 4. Set x su, which represents the desired n-dimensional t variatewith degrees of freedom and correlation matrix C.Repeat<strong>in</strong>g steps 2 to 4 allows one to generate the sequence of multivariatet-distributed random variables.CHAPTER 91. The important attributes of a good risk report are the follow<strong>in</strong>g:Provides <strong>in</strong>sight <strong>in</strong>to the ma<strong>in</strong> sources of relative risk between theportfolio and its benchmark.Is simple and <strong>in</strong>tuitive so that it improves the effectiveness of riskcommunication.Makes it possible to quantify the magnitude of potential underperformanceof the portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st its benchmark and the probabilityof this occurr<strong>in</strong>g.Provides different levels of granularity to meet report<strong>in</strong>g requirementsof different <strong>in</strong>terest groups.2. The standard risk measure used to quantify relative credit risk is track<strong>in</strong>gerror. A forward-look<strong>in</strong>g or ex ante track<strong>in</strong>g error is usually estimated


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 251based on a risk model. Such a risk model, however, is merely a representationof market-driven volatility and correlation observed amongthe modeled risk factors and estimated us<strong>in</strong>g daily or weekly time seriesdata. Because credit risk is the risk of a rare event occurr<strong>in</strong>g, a riskmodel based on a few years of historical data will not adequately capturethe risk.3. The relative credit risk of a portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st a benchmark is def<strong>in</strong>ed asthe risk of a new portfolio constructed such that it has net long andshort exposures to the bonds conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the benchmark and theportfolio. These net long and short positions can be seen as result<strong>in</strong>gfrom tak<strong>in</strong>g the difference between the relative weights of the bonds <strong>in</strong>the portfolio and the relative weights of the bonds <strong>in</strong> the benchmark.Relative credit risk can be quantified us<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g measures:expected loss, unexpected loss, credit value at risk, and expected shortfallrisk.4. The ma<strong>in</strong> advantage of the relative credit risk measures <strong>in</strong>troduced hereover traditional measures is that it allows one to compute both themagnitude and the probability of underperformance of the portfolioaga<strong>in</strong>st its benchmark. Under a lack of knowledge of the shape of thecredit loss distribution, a standard relative risk measure such as track<strong>in</strong>gerror will fail to provide any confidence estimates to the estimatedcredit loss.5. The marg<strong>in</strong>al risk contribution of a bond is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the rate ofchange <strong>in</strong> risk for a small percentage change <strong>in</strong> the bond hold<strong>in</strong>gs.The unexpected loss contribution of the ith bond <strong>in</strong> the portfolio isgiven byna ULC i i1nna UL i ai1n na ai1 k1k1UL P/UL k r ik/UL i UL k r ik UL P 2UL PUL P UL P6. The relative credit risk between the portfolio and the benchmarkarises because of net long and short positions <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dividual bonds.Under the multivariate t distribution, there is greater correlation amongasset returns when large market movements occur. This effect tends tomitigate the relative risk exposure aris<strong>in</strong>g from net long and short positionsbecause asset returns tend to move more <strong>in</strong> tandem dur<strong>in</strong>gextreme market conditions. This expla<strong>in</strong>s why the relative tail risk


252 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSmeasures are lower under the multivariate t-distribution assumptionfor asset returns.7. Obligor asset returns tend to be more correlated dur<strong>in</strong>g periods oflarge market moves when their jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution is modeled as a multivariatet distribution than when they are modeled to have a multivariatenormal distribution. Hence, the credit risk measures of theportfolio are higher under the multivariate t-distribution assumptionthan under the multivariate normal distribution assumption for obligorasset returns.8. As a portfolio manager, I would like to send the follow<strong>in</strong>g risk reportsto the clients:A market risk exposure report that presents measures such as yield,duration, and convexity for the portfolio and the benchmark and thetrack<strong>in</strong>g error aris<strong>in</strong>g from exposure to market risk factors.A credit risk exposure report that quantifies risk measures such asunexpected loss and expected shortfall risk for both the portfolio andthe benchmark, and the relative credit risk quantified us<strong>in</strong>g thesemeasures.A marg<strong>in</strong>al credit risk exposure report highlight<strong>in</strong>g the sources thatcontribute to the relative credit risk between the portfolio and thebenchmark.A credit risk report that is applicable dur<strong>in</strong>g economic contractions,where the recovery rates are lower and asset return correlations arehigher than under the normal economic environment.9. At the 95 percent level of confidence, the scal<strong>in</strong>g factor for comput<strong>in</strong>gVaR is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by solv<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tegral expression:q0.05 1 exp(0.5x 2 )dx22aThis gives 1.645. The appropriate scal<strong>in</strong>g factor for comput<strong>in</strong>gESR at the 95 percent level of confidence is given byl 11 0.95122q x exp(0.5x 2 )dx 2.061.64510. In the portfolio management context, performance attribution refers tothe process of attribut<strong>in</strong>g the excess returns of the portfolio aga<strong>in</strong>st the


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 253benchmark to various sources that contributed to this excess return.<strong>Risk</strong> attribution, on the other hand, refers to the process of attribut<strong>in</strong>gthe relative risk (measured <strong>in</strong> terms of track<strong>in</strong>g error or relative VaR)to various risk factor sources. The performance attribution report helpsthe portfolio manager to communicate the <strong>in</strong>vestment managementprocess more effectively to the client and to attribute the value addedaga<strong>in</strong>st the benchmark to the <strong>in</strong>vestment decisions. Such a report notonly helps to <strong>in</strong>crease the transparency of the <strong>in</strong>vestment process, butalso allows for more discipl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>vestment decisions by the portfoliomanager.11. In a high-grade government bond portfolio, performance is usuallyattributed to the yield curve risk factors such as duration and curverisk. The ma<strong>in</strong> risk drivers <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfolio, however, arechanges <strong>in</strong> the perceived credit quality of the obligors. Because yieldcurve risk factors do not model obligor creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess, a performanceattribution report designed for high-grade government bond portfolioswill be <strong>in</strong>appropriate for a corporate bond portfolio.12. Relevant factors to which performance can be attributed for a corporatebond portfolio <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>dustry sector and obligor credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs.These factors primarily capture the excess returns result<strong>in</strong>g from creditselection. For market risk factors, one could attribute the excessreturns result<strong>in</strong>g from yield curve exposures versus the benchmark.However, <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfolio context, the excess returnsfrom yield curve exposures are usually small and hence could be <strong>in</strong>tegrated<strong>in</strong>to the factors used for expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g credit selection.CHAPTER 101. The benefits of tak<strong>in</strong>g a quantitative approach to portfolio selection arethe follow<strong>in</strong>g:It allows risk analysis to be performed at the portfolio level ratherthan at the bond level.The operational costs are lower because this approach does notrequire ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a large pool of credit analysts.As the number of bond issuers <strong>in</strong> the benchmark <strong>in</strong>creases, itbecomes practically impossible to perform a thorough credit analysisof all issuers, and hence tak<strong>in</strong>g a quantitative approach provides areasonable alternative for bond selection.2. In a quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem, the objective function is quadraticand the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions are l<strong>in</strong>ear. In a nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>gproblem, the objective function and the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions can


254 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSbe any nonl<strong>in</strong>ear function <strong>in</strong> the design variables. The optimal solutionto a nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problem usually occurs at the <strong>in</strong>teriorpo<strong>in</strong>t of the hypercube formed by the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions.Search<strong>in</strong>g for a solution <strong>in</strong>side the hypercube is a time-consum<strong>in</strong>gexercise.3. Because track<strong>in</strong>g error is a quadratic function <strong>in</strong> the portfolio weightsand the constra<strong>in</strong>t functions are l<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>in</strong> the portfolio weights, this isa quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g problem.4. The practical difficulties that can arise when a quantitative approach isused for portfolio construction or rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g are the follow<strong>in</strong>g:Many bonds <strong>in</strong> the optimal portfolio composition may be illiquidand hence difficult to transact.In a portfolio-rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g context, the required number of transactionsand/or turnover may be too large, and therefore, not implementable.5. The answer is no, because the credit risk of the portfolio cannot bemodeled as a l<strong>in</strong>ear function.6. An important requirement when portfolio rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g is performed isto keep the turnover small. Because the optimal portfolio constructionproblem formulation does not take <strong>in</strong>to consideration the exist<strong>in</strong>gbond hold<strong>in</strong>gs, the portfolio turnover will be large if the portfolio constructionproblem is used to rebalance an exist<strong>in</strong>g corporate bond portfolio.7. When portfolios are rebalanced, turnover of the portfolio has to bekept to a m<strong>in</strong>imum <strong>in</strong> order to reduce transaction costs. Impos<strong>in</strong>gturnover constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> a corporate bond portfolio optimization problemis difficult. To overcome this difficulty, one can pose the rebalanc<strong>in</strong>gproblem such that a set of potential sell transactions is first identifiedfrom the exist<strong>in</strong>g portfolio that does not exceed a specifiedmaximum turnover. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the second step, the actual rebalanc<strong>in</strong>gtrades can be identified tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account the sell recommendations.Break<strong>in</strong>g the rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g problem <strong>in</strong>to two steps keeps the complexityof the optimization problem simple while simultaneously impos<strong>in</strong>g theturnover constra<strong>in</strong>t.8. If the objective function of the portfolio-rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g problem is chosento m<strong>in</strong>imize the portfolio turnover, then the optimization problem is anonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g problem. This is because one of the constra<strong>in</strong>tfunctions <strong>in</strong> the optimization problem is the reduction of the activeportfolio’s unexpected loss. Because such a constra<strong>in</strong>t function is quadratic<strong>in</strong> the design variables, the optimization problem is a nonl<strong>in</strong>earprogramm<strong>in</strong>g problem.9. The recovery rate for the obligor is the one that has to be carefullyselected because the composition of the optimal portfolio is most sensitiveto this parameter.


Solutions to End-of-Chapter Questions 255CHAPTER 111. The major similarities between ABSs and CDOs are the follow<strong>in</strong>g:Both are backed by a collateral pool of assets held <strong>in</strong> a bankruptcyremotespecial-purpose vehicle.The rat<strong>in</strong>g of each tranche of an ABS or a CDO is a function of thecredit enhancement, <strong>in</strong>terest and pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payment priorities, andongo<strong>in</strong>g collateral credit performance.The major differences are the follow<strong>in</strong>g:Unlike <strong>in</strong> the case of ABSs, CDOs do not have a service provider.The collateral assets of a CDO can be traded, whereas for ABS thisis not the case.2. The factors that make a CDO attractive from an <strong>in</strong>vestor’s perspectiveare the follow<strong>in</strong>g:A diversified portfolio can be purchased through one trade execution,result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> reduced transaction costs.CDO debt tranches have higher yields than many corporate bonds orasset-backed securities of similar rat<strong>in</strong>g and maturity.Arbitrage CDOs provide an opportunity to ga<strong>in</strong> exposure to thenon-<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade market on a highly diversified basis withoutcommitt<strong>in</strong>g significant resources.3. Subord<strong>in</strong>ation is a form of <strong>in</strong>ternal credit enhancement that is used toprotect senior tranches aga<strong>in</strong>st credit losses. This is achieved by giv<strong>in</strong>g priorityto senior tranches <strong>in</strong> the event of bankruptcy and <strong>in</strong> cash flow tim<strong>in</strong>g.Priority <strong>in</strong> the event of bankruptcy is always strict. Priority <strong>in</strong> cashflows is achieved either through a sequential paydown structure for thedifferent tranches or through a pro rata pr<strong>in</strong>cipal paydown mechanism.4. Par-build<strong>in</strong>g trades are those <strong>in</strong> which collateral asset managers sellbonds that are close to par value and buy bonds that sell at deep discounts.Because for cash flow CDOs collateral coverage tests are basedon the par value of the collateral pool, this practice leads to a decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gcredit quality for the collateral pool, but ensures that the coverage testsare passed. Par-build<strong>in</strong>g trades tend to favor equity <strong>in</strong>vestors at theexpense of senior tranche holders.5. The diversity score of a portfolio represents the equivalent number ofuncorrelated assets <strong>in</strong> a comparison portfolio that exhibits a similardegree of default risk as the orig<strong>in</strong>al portfolio conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g correlatedassets. The diversity score makes it possible to estimate the loss distributionof a portfolio of correlated assets us<strong>in</strong>g a b<strong>in</strong>omial distributionrather than through simulation.6. The ma<strong>in</strong> advantage of us<strong>in</strong>g market value tests for cash flow CDOs isthat they prevent par-build<strong>in</strong>g practices, which tend to favor equitytranche holders at the expense of debt tranche holders. However, the


256 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSuse of market value tests may force an asset manager to trade more frequentlydue to changes <strong>in</strong> the market value of the collateral aris<strong>in</strong>gfrom <strong>in</strong>terest rate changes or rat<strong>in</strong>g changes.7. The relative merits between buy<strong>in</strong>g a CBO and a Tracer of similarmaturity are as follows:Evaluat<strong>in</strong>g the market and credit risks of a Tracer is simpler than fora CBO.Comput<strong>in</strong>g a fair market price for a Tracer is easy and there isgreater pric<strong>in</strong>g transparency.For a CBO, it is possible to choose among different tranche rat<strong>in</strong>gs,but this option does not exist for a Tracer.CBOs are exposed to asset manager risk, but Tracers do not have this.There is considerable market liquidity for Tracers, but CBOs arequite illiquid.


NotesCHAPTER 31. Euro-denom<strong>in</strong>ated corporate bonds are quoted as a spread over theeuro swap curve. The practice of quot<strong>in</strong>g U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated corporatebonds as a spread versus U.S. Treasuries is on the decl<strong>in</strong>e andsome market players are will<strong>in</strong>g to quote corporate bonds as a spreadover the U.S. dollar swap curve.2. The modified duration concept is discussed <strong>in</strong> Chapter 4.3. Portfolio turnover is def<strong>in</strong>ed as one half of the market value of the buyand sell transactions divided by the market value of the portfolio. A simplerdef<strong>in</strong>ition, assum<strong>in</strong>g no <strong>in</strong>jections or withdrawals from the portfolio,is the sum of all buy transactions divided by the size of the portfolio.4. Alan Greenspan, “Lessons from the Global Crises,” Remarks beforethe World Bank Group and the International Monetary Fund, AnnualMeet<strong>in</strong>gs Program of Sem<strong>in</strong>ars, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC, September 27, 1999.5. Nils H. Hakansson, “The Role of a <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong> Market <strong>in</strong> anEconomy—and <strong>in</strong> Avoid<strong>in</strong>g Crisis” (Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper RPF–287), Instituteof Bus<strong>in</strong>ess and Economic Research, University of California,Berkeley, 1999.6. The Lehman Brothers multiverse <strong>in</strong>dex is representative of the<strong>in</strong>vestible universe of fixed-<strong>in</strong>come securities <strong>in</strong> all currencies <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>ghigh-yield bonds.7. William F. Sharpe, “Asset Allocation,” <strong>in</strong> John L. Mag<strong>in</strong>n and DonaldL. Tuttle (eds.), <strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> Investment <strong>Portfolios</strong>: A Dynamic Process,New York: Warren, Gorham & Lamont, 1990.8. 72nd Annual Report, Bank for International Settlements, July 2002, p. 82.9. The duration of reserve portfolios of most central banks is typicallybetween 6 months and 21 months.10. This statement is true under the assumption that the central bank isable to replicate the returns of a broad corporate benchmark. How thiscan be done us<strong>in</strong>g a subset of bonds conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the benchmark isdealt with <strong>in</strong> Chapter 10.11. These changes are reflected <strong>in</strong> the account<strong>in</strong>g rule InternationalAccount<strong>in</strong>g Standard 19 and, <strong>in</strong> the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, <strong>in</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ancialReport<strong>in</strong>g Standard 17.257


258 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSCHAPTER 51. Peter J. Crosbie and Jeffrey R. Bohn, “Model<strong>in</strong>g Default <strong>Risk</strong>,” KMVCorporation, January 2002.2. Jay A. Siegel, Robert Young, and Edward Young, “Analysis of Rat<strong>in</strong>gL<strong>in</strong>kages Between Manufacturers and Their F<strong>in</strong>ance Subsidiaries,”Moody’s Investors Service, November 2001.3. David T. Hamilton, Richard Cantor, and Sharon Ou, “Default andRecovery Rates of <strong>Corporate</strong> Issuers,” Moody’s Investors Service,February 2002, p. 16.4. See, for example, Karen VandeCastle and David Keisman, “Recover<strong>in</strong>gYour Money: Insights Into Losses from Defaults,” Standard & PoorsCorporation, 1999; Karen VandeCastle, “Suddenly Structure Mattered:Insights <strong>in</strong>to Recoveries of Defaulted Debt,” Standard & PoorsCorporation, May 2000; David T. Hamilton, Richard Cantor, andSharon Ou, “Default and Recovery Rates of <strong>Corporate</strong> Issuers,”Moody’s Investors Service, February 2002.5. Edward I. Altman, Andrea Resti, and Andrea Sironi, “The L<strong>in</strong>kBetween Default and Recovery Rates: Effects on the Procyclicality ofRegulatory Capital” (Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 113), Bank for InternationalSettlements, July 2002.6. Edw<strong>in</strong> J. Elton, Mart<strong>in</strong> J. Gruber, Deepak Agrawal, and ChristopherMann, “Factors Affect<strong>in</strong>g the Valuation of <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong>s” (Work<strong>in</strong>gPaper), Stern Bus<strong>in</strong>ess School, New York University, 2002.CHAPTER 61. Sanjiv R. Das, Laurence Freed, Gary Geng, and Nikunj Kapadia, “CorrelatedDefault <strong>Risk</strong>” (Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 01/02-22-WP), Santa Clara University,Santa Clara, CA, January 2002.2. B<strong>in</strong> Zeng and J<strong>in</strong>g Zhang, “Measur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Credit</strong> Correlations: EquityCorrelations are not Enough!” KMV Corporation, January 2002.3. See Chapter 8 <strong>in</strong> Greg M. Gupton, Christopher C. F<strong>in</strong>ger, and MickeyBhatia, <strong>Credit</strong>Metrics (Technical Document), New York: <strong>Risk</strong>MetricsGroup, April 1997.4. Stephen Kealhofer and Jeffrey R. Bohn, “Portfolio Management ofDefault <strong>Risk</strong>,” KMV Corporation, May 2001.CHAPTER 71. For a discussion of f<strong>in</strong>ance applications of Monte Carlo techniques, seeBruno Dupire (ed.), Monte Carlo: Methodologies and Applications forPric<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>Risk</strong> Management, London: <strong>Risk</strong> Books, 1998.


Notes 2592. For details, see William H. Press, Saul A. Teukolsky, William T. Vetterl<strong>in</strong>g,and Brian P. Flannery, Numerical Recipes <strong>in</strong> C: The Art of Scientific Comput<strong>in</strong>g,Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993, pp. 287–289.3. If the estimated covariance matrix C happens to be s<strong>in</strong>gular, one canadd a small diagonal perturbation matrix to C as expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Chapter2 to make it positive def<strong>in</strong>ite.4. For a discussion of importance sampl<strong>in</strong>g, see Paul Glasserman, PhilipHeidelberger, and Perwez Shahabudd<strong>in</strong>, “Variance Reduction Techniquesfor Estimat<strong>in</strong>g Value-at-<strong>Risk</strong>,” Management Science, Vol. 46,No. 10, October 2000, pp. 1349–1369.5. For a discussion of the relative merits of value at risk and expectedshortfall, see Yasuhiro Yamai and Tosh<strong>in</strong>ao Yoshiba, “On the Validityof Value-at-<strong>Risk</strong>: Comparative Analyses with Expected Shortfall”(IMES Discussion Paper No. 2001-E-4), Bank of Japan, 2001.CHAPTER 81. For an empirical study of fitt<strong>in</strong>g alternate jo<strong>in</strong>t distribution functions tomodel correlated defaults, see Sanjiv R. Das and Gary Geng, “Model<strong>in</strong>gthe Processes of Correlated Default” (Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper), Santa ClaraUniversity, Santa Clara, CA, May 2002.2. Rüdiger Frey, Alexander J. McNeil, and Mark A. Nyfeler, “Model<strong>in</strong>gDependent Defaults: Asset Correlations Are Not Enough!” (<strong>Risk</strong>LabResearch Paper), retrieved from www.risklab.ch March 2001.3. Charles W. Dunnett and Milton Sobel, “A Bivariate Generalizationof Student’s t-Distribution with Tables for Certa<strong>in</strong> Special Cases,”Biometrika, Vol. 41, 1954, pp. 153–169.CHAPTER 91. For an exposition of risk model<strong>in</strong>g for fixed-<strong>in</strong>come portfolios, see LevDynk<strong>in</strong> and Jay Hyman, “Multi-Factor Fixed-Income <strong>Risk</strong> Models andTheir Applications,” pp. 665–696 <strong>in</strong> Frank J. Fabozzi and Harry M.Markowitz (eds.), The Theory and Practice of Investment Management,New York: Wiley, 2002.2. See, for example, Srichander Ramaswamy, “Fixed Income PortfolioManagement: <strong>Risk</strong> Model<strong>in</strong>g, Portfolio Construction and PerformanceAttribution,” Journal of Performance Measurement, Vol. 5, Summer2001, pp. 58–70; Lev Dynk<strong>in</strong>, Jay Hyman, and Vadim Konstant<strong>in</strong>ovsky,“A Return Attribution Model for Fixed Income Securities,”Chapter 21 <strong>in</strong> Frank J. Fabozzi (ed.), Handbook of Portfolio Management,New York: Wiley, 1998.


260 MANAGING CREDIT RISK IN CORPORATE BOND PORTFOLIOSCHAPTER 101. Srichander Ramaswamy, “<strong>Manag<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Credit</strong> <strong>Risk</strong> <strong>in</strong> a <strong>Corporate</strong> <strong>Bond</strong>Portfolio,” Journal of Portfolio Management, Vol. 28, Spr<strong>in</strong>g 2002,pp. 67–72.2. Edward I. Altman and Vellore M. Kishore, “Almost Everyth<strong>in</strong>g YouWanted to Know about Recoveries on Defaulted <strong>Bond</strong>s,” F<strong>in</strong>ancialAnalysts Journal, November/December 1996, pp. 57–64.3. In a practical sett<strong>in</strong>g, one could use Moody’s methodology for predict<strong>in</strong>grecovery rates on defaulted bonds. See Greg M. Gupton and RogerM. Ste<strong>in</strong>, “LossCalc TM : Moody’s Model for Predict<strong>in</strong>g Loss GivenDefault (LGD),” Moody’s Investors Service, February 2002.CHAPTER 111. Market value transactions use <strong>in</strong>stead a m<strong>in</strong>imum net worth test. Thistest requires that the excess market value of the collateral after tak<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>to account all debt due never falls below a certa<strong>in</strong> percentage of theequity face value. This test is performed for each debt tranche, with atypical percentage for senior debt at 60 percent of equity.2. Collateral quality guidel<strong>in</strong>es will <strong>in</strong>dicate whether this is permitted ornot.3. Excess spread refers to the difference between the <strong>in</strong>terest rate earnedon the collateral assets and the <strong>in</strong>terest rate paid to the CDO debt holders.Excess spread provides an additional layer of loss protection to seniordebt holders.4. For a discussion on par-build<strong>in</strong>g trad<strong>in</strong>g practices, see David Tesher,“CDO Spotlight: Par-Build<strong>in</strong>g Trades Merit Scrut<strong>in</strong>y,” Standard &Poor’s Corporation, July 2002.5. In Chapter 6, I showed that the expected loss of a portfolio compris<strong>in</strong>gdefaultable securities is not dependent on the correlation betweenobligor defaults <strong>in</strong> the portfolio. On the basis of this <strong>in</strong>formation, onemay suspect that the notion of diversification <strong>in</strong> the underly<strong>in</strong>g collateralportfolio is irrelevant for purposes of estimat<strong>in</strong>g expected loss. Infact, by tak<strong>in</strong>g a bond portfolio for which Moody’s assigns a rat<strong>in</strong>g, Ishow <strong>in</strong> the last section of this chapter that Moody’s credit rat<strong>in</strong>g canbe <strong>in</strong>ferred without model<strong>in</strong>g the asset return correlation between theobligors <strong>in</strong> the portfolio.6. For a discussion on CDO valuation methodology and deriv<strong>in</strong>g impliedcredit rat<strong>in</strong>gs, see Sivan Mahadevan and David Schwartz, “CDOInsights: A Framework for Secondary Market CDO Valuation,”Morgan Stanley Fixed Income Research, October 2001.


Notes 2617. For details, see Sten Bergman, “CDO Evaluator Applies Correlationand Monte Carlo Simulation to Determ<strong>in</strong>e Portfolio Quality,” Standard& Poor’s Corporation, November 2001.8. The adjustment factor used here is reported <strong>in</strong> a study by DomenicoPicone, “Collateralised Debt Obligations,” retrieved from www.defaultrisk.com/pdf—files/Collateralised—Debt—Obligations.pdf September2002.9. Fitch rat<strong>in</strong>g factors are given <strong>in</strong> “Rat<strong>in</strong>g Criteria for Cash Flow CollateralizedDebt Obligations,” (Loan Products Special Report), p. 6, FitchRat<strong>in</strong>gs, November 2000.10. Exposure to a broad basket of corporate bonds can also be acquired bytrad<strong>in</strong>g synthetic Tracers issued by Morgan Stanley. Recently issuedsynthetic Tracers use a pool of 100 equally weighted credit defaultswaps to represent the exposure to the U.S. <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporatebond market.11. For exchange-traded bond funds, the adm<strong>in</strong>istrative fee is around 15basis po<strong>in</strong>ts.12. This tends to make the accrued <strong>in</strong>terest calculations for Tracers differentfrom those for conventional bonds, and sometimes these are a challengeto back-office account<strong>in</strong>g.13. The use of a tail risk measure to derive an implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g for theportfolio shares many common pr<strong>in</strong>ciples with the way economic riskcapital is allocated <strong>in</strong> banks to target desired solvency standards.


IndexABS. See Asset-backed securitiesAccount deficits, 42Account<strong>in</strong>g rules. See Pension fundsAccrued <strong>in</strong>terest, 25, 52calculations, 261Active duration bet, 171Active portfolio, 161credit risk measures, <strong>in</strong>crease, 167unexpected loss, 193m<strong>in</strong>imization, 184Actuarial ga<strong>in</strong>s/losses. See Net cumulativeunrecognized actuarial ga<strong>in</strong>s/lossesActuarial liabilities, 242. See also Pension fundscomputation, 48, 49cover<strong>in</strong>g, 47Aggregates. See Portfolio credit riskAgrawal, Deepak, 89, 258Alpha. See Shape parameterAltman, Edward, 258, 260Annual returns, fluctuation, 40Antithetic sampl<strong>in</strong>g, 131, 151usage, 136Arbitrage CDOs, 211contrast. See Balance sheet CDOsperformance, 214Asset allocation decision, 49Asset classes, 37–38. See also Fixed-<strong>in</strong>come assetscorrelation, 39historical performance, 45hold<strong>in</strong>g, 50Asset return, 107, 112. See also Obligorsco-movement, 125, 140, 142decomposition, 108distribution, 148generation. See Correlated asset returnsjo<strong>in</strong>t distribution, 3–4, 143–146, 151, 154marg<strong>in</strong>al distribution, 125multivariate normal distribution assumption, 149multivariate t distribution assumptions, 156nondiversifiable component, 108normal distribution assumption, relaxation, 9vector, simulation, 128volatility, 71, 73Asset return correlation, 106, 109–110, 146. See alsoTotal asset return correlationapproximation, 109–111differences, 121estimation, 104–111<strong>in</strong>crease, 167matrix, 159Asset-backed securities (ABS), 207, 211, 255transactions, 215Assetshold<strong>in</strong>gs, restrictions, 34long-term return, 48manager, 214risk, 220maturity, 227size, 227transfer, 213values, 102volatilities, 102Attribution. See Performance attributionmodel, 172–175Auto loans, 26BAC. See Basic <strong>in</strong>dustries and chemicalsBack-office account<strong>in</strong>g, 261Balance sheetdate, 48transactions, 210Balance sheet CDOs, arbitrage CDOs (contrast),207–209Banklend<strong>in</strong>g, 33loan, tak<strong>in</strong>g, 32Bank of New York, securities (deposit<strong>in</strong>g), 231Bank<strong>in</strong>gcrisis, 32system, liquidity (<strong>in</strong>jection), 33Bankruptcy. See Parent companyevent, 25, 255laws, 34remoteness, provid<strong>in</strong>g, 26Bankruptcy-remote SPV, 207, 210Barclays Global Investors. See iShares GSInvesTopBase currency. See PortfolioBasic <strong>in</strong>dustries and chemicals (BAC), 110Benchmark. See <strong>Corporate</strong> bonds; Investment-gradebenchmarkcomposition, 179, 192downside risk, 163issuers, <strong>in</strong>crease, 2marketrisk characteristics, 195value, 192outperformance, 171portfolio, 132, 158, 163, 191constituent bonds, 157risk factor, 64risk-return characteristics, 183underperformance, 160weights, 193Benchmark-neutral positions, deviation, 170Bergman, Sten, 261Bernoulli distribution, 8Bernoulli random variable, 8, 98default <strong>in</strong>dicator, 99variance, 87BET. See B<strong>in</strong>omial expansion techniqueBeta. See Scale parameterfunctions, f<strong>in</strong>ite sums (usage). See Incomplete betafunctionsBeta distribution, 9, 22, 129, 238choice, 76mean/variance, 9usage, 10Bhatia, Mickey, 258Bid prices, decrease, 30262


Index 263Bid-ask spread, 27, 50decrease, 29<strong>in</strong>crease, 28B<strong>in</strong>omial distribution, 237B<strong>in</strong>omial expansion technique (BET), 222–225Bivariate t distribution, 144–146Bivariate t probability computation, C programimplementation, 151–154Bohn, Jeffrey, 258<strong>Bond</strong>-level credit risk, 71<strong>Bond</strong>s. See Investment-grade bonds; Non<strong>in</strong>vestmentgradebondsauctions, 231certificate, 23collateralization, 3, 24–26convexity, 90coupon, 89dirty price, 185duration, 90embedded options, <strong>in</strong>clusion, 52, 54–56yield changes, 54expected losses, 234expected recovery rate, 89face value, 52hold<strong>in</strong>g, change, 161<strong>in</strong>surer, 215<strong>in</strong>vestment, nom<strong>in</strong>al amount, 65issuers, credit analysis, 179issues, nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure, 187marg<strong>in</strong>al risk contribution, 251market. See <strong>Corporate</strong> bond marketturnover. See Government bondsmark-to-market value, 128modified duration, 29nom<strong>in</strong>al amount, 94nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure, 163par value, 10, 22portfolio. See Government bondmanagement, 118pricechange, 53sensitivity, 52price-yield relationship, 53relative weights, 181repric<strong>in</strong>g, 89selection, 2trad<strong>in</strong>g cost, 29unavailability, 219unexpected losses, 234yields, 49, 90Book-entry bonds, 24Book-entry securities, 24Box-Muller method, 125Boyle, Pheim, 124Call option, 54Call provision, 27Callable bondsdirty price, 55Callable bonds, price, 54Cantor, Richard, 258Capitalmarkets, 41development, 32structure, 211–218. See also Collateralized debtobligationsCaptive f<strong>in</strong>ance companies, 75Cash CDOs, synthetic CDOs (contrast), 210Cash deposits, earn<strong>in</strong>gs, 219Cash flowanalysis, 228capacity, 24CDOs, 216market value CDOs (contrast), 209tranche, credit rat<strong>in</strong>g (determ<strong>in</strong>ation), 222priorities, 221Cash <strong>in</strong>jections, re<strong>in</strong>vestment, 183Cash, <strong>in</strong>terest rate (earn<strong>in</strong>gs), 57CBOs. See Collateralized bond obligationsCCL. See Consumer cyclicalCDO Evaluator, 226–227CDOs. See Collateralized debt obligationsCell-<strong>in</strong>dex<strong>in</strong>g strategy, 178–179Central banksobjectives, change, 41–43reserves, 40–47Central moments, 7. See also Second central momentCharitable trusts, 212Chi-square-distributed random variable, degrees offreedom, 9, 141Cholesky decomposition, 16–17, 240Cholesky factor, 127Cholesky factorization, 16Clean price, 52Client-report<strong>in</strong>g requirements, 172CLOs. See Collateralized loan obligationsClosed-end mortgage bonds, 25CNC. See Consumer noncyclicalCoefficient of correlation, 11Co<strong>in</strong>s, toss<strong>in</strong>g, 5, 12outcomes, 6Collateral. See Debtassets, 220pool, 222values, 226coverage test, 217–218pledge, 23quality, 236tests, 216–217trust bonds, 25value, 26Collateral pool, 209deterioration, 220issuers. See Collateralized debt obligationsleveraged <strong>in</strong>strument, 211par value, 255price volatility, 226risk-return profile, 220Collateral portfolio, 217default rate distribution, 226diversification, 223diversity score, 222–223market value, 225SDR, 228Collateralization. See <strong>Bond</strong>sCollateralized bond obligations (CBOs), 209, 256Collateralized debt obligations (CDOs), 4, 207–211, 255attractiveness, 236capital structure, 213collateral pool issuers, 221contrast. See Balance sheet CDOs; Cash CDOs;Cash flowcredit risk, evaluation, 206debt tranches, 211, 215. See also Subord<strong>in</strong>atedCDO debt tranches<strong>in</strong>vestor motivations, 210–211life, 224notes, 215issuance, 220liabilities, 219


264 INDEXCollateralized debt obligations (cont<strong>in</strong>ued)parties, 214–215rat<strong>in</strong>g. See Market value CDOsrisk, sources, 218–220securities, collection, 206structure, 212, 221, 225subclassification, 207tranches, 212, 217, 227expected loss, computation, 225rat<strong>in</strong>g, 215Collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) transactionanatomy, 211–218clos<strong>in</strong>g date, 214evolution, 213–214Fitch, rat<strong>in</strong>gs method, 229–230Moody’s, method, 222–226rat<strong>in</strong>g, 221–229Standard & Poor’s, method, 226–228Collateralized loan obligations (CLOs), 208Communication and technology (COT), 110Compact notation, usage, 14Computational efficiency, improvement, 132Concentration limit. See IndustryConditional VaR, 134Confidence level, 134, 168. See also Expectedshortfall risk; Lossmeasurement, 133Conglomerates, 23Constra<strong>in</strong>ts. See Market risk; Turnoverfunctions, 185. See also <strong>Portfolios</strong>etup. See Optimization problemsConsumer cyclical (CCL), 110Consumer noncyclical (CNC), 110Contagion behavior. See F<strong>in</strong>ancial marketsContemporaneous defaults, probability, 80Cont<strong>in</strong>uous distribution, 6–7Cont<strong>in</strong>uous-time stochastic process, 12Convexity, 53. See also <strong>Bond</strong>s; Effective convexity;Effective portfolio; Option-adjusted convexitymeasures, 53<strong>Corporate</strong> action, 231<strong>Corporate</strong> benchmark, 257<strong>Corporate</strong> bond market, 3, 23endnotes, 257questions, 50solutions, 240–243<strong>Corporate</strong> bond portfolio, 253base currency, 61credit risk, quantification, 8downside risk, 47expected return, 186management, 2managers, 132, 172market risk, 156risk exposures, 1selection, 177<strong>Corporate</strong> bonds. See Unsecuritized corporate bonds;U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong>vestment-gradecorporate bondsbaskets. See Tradeable corporate bond basketstrad<strong>in</strong>g, 230–235benchmark, 65bid sizes, decrease, 28credit risk determ<strong>in</strong>ants, 3credit spreads, 47evidence, 40–50features, 23–28hold<strong>in</strong>g period, <strong>in</strong>crease, 27<strong>in</strong>dex, 38return, 40<strong>in</strong>vestment, 44downside risk, computation, 46issuance, 36liquidity, fluctuations, 29market capitalization, 35, 36outperformance. See U.S. Treasuriesportfoliomanagement, 31managers, 30reasons, 45–47role, 32–35trad<strong>in</strong>g, 28–32costs, 28–30, 50, 241turnover, frequency, 29yield, 245<strong>Corporate</strong> borrowers, credit spreads (<strong>in</strong>crease), 28<strong>Corporate</strong> credit exposures, 230<strong>Corporate</strong> portfolio managers, 30<strong>Corporate</strong> portfolios, performance, 47<strong>Corporate</strong> reorganization, 34<strong>Corporate</strong>s, assessment, 34Corporationscontribution, 47fund<strong>in</strong>g sources, 35Correlated asset returns, generation, 126–127Correlation. See Asset classes; Coefficient ofcorrelation; Default; Equity returnscoefficient, 38estimation. See Asset return correlationmatrix, 127structure, 143Cost-benefit analysis, 42COT. See Communication and technologyCounterparty. See Hedge counterpartyCovariance, 11. See also Equity returns; RandomvariableCovariance matrix, 16–17, 19, 127, 259. See alsoSecurity; Yieldeigenvalues. See n n covariance matrixeigenvector decomposition, 21normalized eigenvectors, 20Coverage test. See Collateral<strong>Credit</strong>allocation preferences. See Government-<strong>in</strong>ducedcredit allocation preferencesassessment skills, 34crunch, 33default swap, 210enhancement. See Structural credit enhancement<strong>in</strong>ternal/external forms, 26event. See Issuer-specific credit events; Multistatecredit eventcorrelation, 95probability, determ<strong>in</strong>ation, 8migration, 229rat<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>g. See Implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>gselection, 253spreads, 219narrow<strong>in</strong>g, 40underwrit<strong>in</strong>g skills, 229<strong>Credit</strong> card receivables, 26<strong>Credit</strong> loss. See Two-bond portfoliocomputation, 128–130. See also Jo<strong>in</strong>t credit lossdistribution, 97, 138, 248. See also <strong>Portfolios</strong>tandard deviation, 132simulation, 125–132<strong>Credit</strong> rat<strong>in</strong>g, deterioration, 74<strong>Credit</strong> risk, 26, 27, 218. See also <strong>Bond</strong>-level creditrisk; Portfolio credit riskcomputations, 9


Index 265contribution. See Marg<strong>in</strong>al credit risk contributiondeterm<strong>in</strong>ants. See <strong>Corporate</strong> bondselements, 67–81estimation, 80evaluation. See Collateralized debt obligations<strong>in</strong>crease, 45level, 69measures, 198. See also Relative credit riskillustration. See Interest<strong>in</strong>crease. See Active portfoliomigration mode, 111–118parameters. See Two-bond portfolioquantification, 10, 81–92, 95, 199. See also<strong>Corporate</strong> bond portfolioreport<strong>in</strong>g, 4<strong>Credit</strong> risk managementmathematics, 5questions, 21–22solutions, 237–240motivation, 1–2<strong>Credit</strong> risk model<strong>in</strong>put variables, 167parameters, 199change, 191<strong>Credit</strong> risk model<strong>in</strong>g, 67endnotes, 258questions, 94solutions, 243–245<strong>Credit</strong> spreads, <strong>in</strong>crease. See <strong>Corporate</strong> borrowers<strong>Credit</strong> value at risk (CrVaR), 132–133. See alsoRelative CrVaR<strong>Credit</strong>-event-driven scenario analysis, 221<strong>Credit</strong>Metrics, 108Technical Document, 200<strong>Credit</strong>worth<strong>in</strong>ess. See IssuersCrosbie, Peter, 258Cross-default clauses, 70, 71CrVaR. See <strong>Credit</strong> value at riskCurrency markets, 63Currency reserves, composition, 43–45Curvature, 58Das, Sanjiv, 258, 259Data reduction, achievement, 58Debenture bonds, 24–25Debenture holders, position, 25Debtcomponents. See <strong>Risk</strong>-free debt componentsface value, 104f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g, 32issuecollateral/seniority, 70seniority, 89obligationssecur<strong>in</strong>g, 25servic<strong>in</strong>g, 28payment obligations. See Outstand<strong>in</strong>g debttranches. See Collateralized debt obligations; Seniordebt tranchesvaluation, structural model (Merton), 104Debt-to-equity ratio, 32, 102Decomposition. See Cholesky decomposition;Eigenvalues; MatrixDefault. See Probability of defaultcorrelation, 98–104, 145differences, 121estimation, 100–102relationship. See Lossevent, 23. See Issuersjo<strong>in</strong>t probability, 101LD, 91, 116Merton approach, 71–73, 244mode, 126. See also Expected loss; Portfolio creditrisk; Two-bond portfolio; Unexpected lossusage, 187po<strong>in</strong>t, logarithm, 72probability, 80probability estimates, 81rates. See Scenario default ratesdistribution, 226–227. See also Collateral portfoliosimulation, 227risk, 27Default mode (PDM), 189Defaulted bonds, recovery rate, 244process, 10Defaulted securities, supply, 88Def<strong>in</strong>ite matrix. See Positive-def<strong>in</strong>ite matrixDegrees of freedom, 149–151. See also Chi-squaredistributedrandom variableDelta, 55. See OptionsDensity function, 149. See also Jo<strong>in</strong>t density function;ProbabilityDesign variables, 254. See also OptimizationproblemsDiagonal elements, 14, 15. See also Off-diagonalelementsDiagonal matrix, 15, 17–18Diagonalization. See MatrixDie, roll<strong>in</strong>g, 5, 12, 21–22outcomes, 6Direction vectors, 19–22. See also Normalizeddirection vectorsDirty price, 54, 65, 85. See also <strong>Bond</strong>s; Callable bondsDisability rates, assumptions, 48Discount rate, usage. See Pension liabilitiesDiscrete distribution, 6Discrete jo<strong>in</strong>t probability distribution, 114Discrete probability tree, variables (number), 125Discrete zero-one random variable, 8Discrete-state stochastic process, 12Discrete-time Markov cha<strong>in</strong>, 13Discrete-time stochastic process, 12–13Distressed debt, 209Distributed random variable, 22Distribution. See Beta distribution; Cont<strong>in</strong>uousdistribution; <strong>Credit</strong> loss; Discrete distribution;Jo<strong>in</strong>t probabilitiescomputation. See Returnsflatness, 7kurtosis, 7mean, 6–8peakedness, 7pth quantile, 7simulation. See Loss distributionskewness, 7symmetry, 8variance, 7, 8Diversification, 38. See also Industrybenefits. See Reservesdegree, 226efficiency, 2<strong>in</strong>crease, 40Diversity score, 255. See also Collateralcalculation, 223Dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated assetscomposition, 45official hold<strong>in</strong>gs, 43–44Dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated reserve assets, equities(proportion), 44Downgrade risk, 27


266 INDEXDownside risk, 156, 172. See also Benchmark;Portfoliocontrol, 51Dunnett, Charles, 259Dupire, Bruno, 258Duration. See <strong>Bond</strong>s; Effective duration; Effectiveportfolio; Modified duration; Option-adjusteddurationbet. See Active duration betDynk<strong>in</strong>, Lev, 259Economic contractionsperiods, 27risk report<strong>in</strong>g, 165–167Economic crises, 33, 42Economic downturn, 102Economic recession, 242Economic risk, 26–28EDF. See Expected default frequencyEffective convexity, 55–57. See also PortfolioEffective duration, 55, 56Effective portfolioconvexity, 56duration, 56Effective yield, 56Efficient portfolio selection, conceptual framework,184Eigenvalues, 15, 18. See also Matrix; n ncovariance matrix; Non-negative eigenvalues;Square matrixdecomposition, 239Eigenvectors, 15. See also Symmetric matrixdecomposition. See Covariance matrixEL. See Expected lossELp. See Expected portfolio lossElton, Edw<strong>in</strong> J., 89, 258Empirical approach. See DefaultEmployers, f<strong>in</strong>ancial statements, 48Energy (ENE), 110Equipment trust certificates, 26Equitiescomponents, 106<strong>in</strong>vestments, 44market, 81rally, 40prices, changes, 105proportion. See Dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated reserve assetstranches, 212Equity returnscorrelation, 105, 109–110covariance, 247volatilities, 45ESR. See Expected shortfall riskETF. See Exchange-traded fundEuro swap curves, 64Euro-denom<strong>in</strong>ated corporate bonds, 257Ex ante track<strong>in</strong>g errors, 156, 250–251Excess kurtosis, 139Excess returns, 174Exchange rates, 41risk, 61factor, 64Exchange-traded bond funds, 261Exchange-traded fund (ETF), 230Expected asset value at maturity, logarithm, 72Expected default frequency (EDF)(KMV Corporation)one-year, usage, 200usage, 72–74, 103–104, 145values, 74, 204Expected loss (EL). See Two-bond portfoliocomputation, 85, 130–131. See also Collateralizeddebt obligationsillustration, 92–94default mode, 83–86denotation, 117derivation, 91migration mode, 88–91ratio, 204usage, 249Expected portfolio loss (ELp), 96, 130, 145, 148Expected recovery rate. See <strong>Bond</strong>sExpected return. See <strong>Corporate</strong> bond portfolioExpected shortfall risk (ESR), 132–135, 151, 163. Seealso Relative ESRcomputation, 176confidence level, 235percentage, 170usage, 249, 252Expected value, 6–8, 38def<strong>in</strong>ition. See Random variableproduct, 11Face value, percentage, 75Factor models, 106–109, 247concept. See KMV CorporationFactor variances, 60Fat tails, 248Fat-tailed distribution, 248F<strong>in</strong>ance, open problem, 142F<strong>in</strong>ancial assets, 25F<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions, 109F<strong>in</strong>ancial loss, 81F<strong>in</strong>ancial markets, contagion/herd<strong>in</strong>g behavior, 140F<strong>in</strong>ancial obligations, honor<strong>in</strong>g, 24. See also Seniorunsecured f<strong>in</strong>ancial obligationsF<strong>in</strong>ancial sector, subclassifications, 111F<strong>in</strong>ancial securities, risk assessment, 246F<strong>in</strong>ancial services (FIN), 111companies, 23F<strong>in</strong>ancial statements. See EmployersF<strong>in</strong>ancial subsidiary, 75F<strong>in</strong>ancials, 173F<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g costs, 48F<strong>in</strong>ger, Christopher, 258F<strong>in</strong>ite sums, usage. See Incomplete beta functionsFirm-specific component, 107First mortgage bonds, 25Fitch Rat<strong>in</strong>gsfactors, 229method. See Collateralized debt obligationstransactionrat<strong>in</strong>gs, 234, 261Fixed yield spread, 89Fixed-<strong>in</strong>come assets. See U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>atedfixed-<strong>in</strong>come assetsclasses, 35Fixed-<strong>in</strong>come securities, pension assets (proportion),49Fixed-rate coupons, payment, 218–219Flannery, Brian, 259Ford Motor <strong>Credit</strong>, 106Foreign currency reserveshold<strong>in</strong>g, 242level, 42–43proportion, 41Foreign debt. See Short-term foreign debtForward-look<strong>in</strong>g estimates, 106Freed, Laurence, 258Frey, Rüdiger, 259


Index 267Fund<strong>in</strong>g requirements, 41Fung, Ben, 44Gamma, 55. See also Optionsfunction, 76, 142Gamma distribution, 8–9, 149mean, 9variance, 9Generalized hyperbolic distribution, 141Geng, Gary, 258, 259Glasserman, Paul, 259Government bonds, 50, 90. See also High-gradegovernment bondsissuance, 34market, turnover, 28portfolio, 1management, 30Government <strong>in</strong>terference, absence, 34Government-<strong>in</strong>duced credit allocation preferences, 34Greenspan, Alan, 33, 257Growth rate, 71Gruber, Mart<strong>in</strong> J., 89, 258Gupton, Greg, 258, 260Hakansson, Nils, 33, 34, 257Hamilton, David, 258Hedge counterparty, 215Heidelberger, Philip, 259Herd<strong>in</strong>g behavior. See F<strong>in</strong>ancial marketsHigh-default periods, 88High-grade government bonds, 176High-return asset, 208High-yield assets, 209High-yield bonds, 24, 211self-amortiz<strong>in</strong>g pool, 209Historical data, limitation, 8Historical default, 70probabilities, 118Historical PD, usage, 103–104, 145Historical performance, 37–40. See also Asset classes;Investment-grade corporate bondsanalysis, purpose, 50, 241Historical track<strong>in</strong>g errors, 156Historical transition probability, 78Historical volatilities, usage, 62Home-equity loans, 26Homogeneous Markov cha<strong>in</strong>, 13Hyman, Jay, 259IC. See Interest coverageIdentity matrix, 14–15Illiquidity, 29Implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g, 233–235. See also Structuredcredit products<strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>g, 128Implied yield volatility<strong>in</strong>crease, 169risk factor, 63Importance sampl<strong>in</strong>g, 131–132Incentive structure, absence, 45Incomplete beta functions, f<strong>in</strong>ite sums (usage), 151–154Indentures, 23Independence assumption, 87–88Industrial companies, 23Industrial sectorphysical asset, 76subclassifications, 110Industrials, 173Industryconcentration limit, 216–217diversification, 229exposures, 229Inflation rates, progression, 48Input parameters, 191Input variables. See <strong>Credit</strong> riskINR. See Insurance and reitsInstitutional <strong>in</strong>vestor base, stability (absence), 34Insurance and reits (INR), 111, 164Integral limits, 144Interestcredit risk measures, illustration, 135–138<strong>in</strong>vestment horizon, 24portfolio credit risk quantities, 118, 233risk-free rate, 104Interest coverage (IC) tests, 217–218, 229Interest rate risk, 27, 51–56, 218–219control, 53<strong>in</strong>crease, 45Interest rateschanges, 210payment, 42swaps, 219Intermediaries, 29Intermediation, failure, 33Inverse. See MatrixInvestmentdecisions, 253risks, 37horizon. See Interestmanagement process, 171manager, 170maturity, 45–46risks, 26–28Investment-grade benchmark, 178Investment-grade bonds, 70Investment-grade commercial/<strong>in</strong>dustrial loans, 208Investment-grade corporate bonds, 30historical performance, 37<strong>in</strong>dex, 40performance, 45portfolio, 230returnscorrelation coefficient. See Standard & Poor’sU.S. Treasury returns, correlation, 38Investment-grade obligor, 18Investors. See Long-term <strong>in</strong>vestorsmotivations. See Collateralized debt obligationsiShares GS InvesTop (Barclays Global Investors),230Issuersbonds, <strong>in</strong>vestment, 86credit analysis. See <strong>Bond</strong>screditworth<strong>in</strong>ess, 88default, 84event, 31probabilities, 73nom<strong>in</strong>al value, 85PDassessment, framework, 77<strong>in</strong>crease, 88placement, 31static pool, 70Issuer-specific credit events, 88Issuer-specific risk, 61Jo<strong>in</strong>t credit loss, computation, 114–116Jo<strong>in</strong>t default, probability, 99, 102–104, 140computation, 145estimation, 100–101Jo<strong>in</strong>t density function, 11


268 INDEXJo<strong>in</strong>t distributions, 10–12. See also Asset returnfunctions, 5states, 112Jo<strong>in</strong>t migration probabilities, computation, 114,145–148Jo<strong>in</strong>t probabilities, 116distributions, 10–11. See also Discrete jo<strong>in</strong>tprobability distributionJunior mortgage bonds, 25Kapadia, Nikunj, 258Kealhofer, Stephen, 258Keisman, David, 258Kishore, Vellore, 260KMV Corporation. See Expected default frequency;Probability of defaultapproach, 94, 244factor model concept, 108framework, 143, 190study, 106, 109Konstant<strong>in</strong>ovsky, Vadim, 259Kurtosis. See Distribution; Excess kurtosis;Leptokurtosisdef<strong>in</strong>ition, 7property. See LeptokurtosisLD. See Loss on defaultLehman Brothers. See Targeted ReturnIndex Securitiescorporate bondsdatabase, 89<strong>in</strong>dex, market capitalization, 27global multiverse <strong>in</strong>dex, 35Leptokurtosis, property, 139Leverage ratio, 105, 109, 247LGD. See Loss given defaultLiabilities. See Pension liabilitiesbook value, 73cover<strong>in</strong>g. See Actuarial liabilitiesL<strong>in</strong>ear algebra, 2, 13–21L<strong>in</strong>ear factor model, 107L<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g, 180–181problems, 180solv<strong>in</strong>g, 181Liquidation, 34loss, 210Liquidityfluctuations. See <strong>Corporate</strong> bondsmanagement, 41–42portfolio, 41requirements, 43risk, 26, 27, 219Local bond issuance, access restriction, 34Local issuance, costs, 34Log-normal process, 71Long-term dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated reserves, non-Treasurycomponent, 44Long-term <strong>in</strong>vestors, 40Long-term liabilities, 72Losscomputation. See <strong>Credit</strong>; Jo<strong>in</strong>t credit lossdata, usage. See Simulated loss datadistribution, 83scenario. See Worst-case loss scenarioseverity, measurement, 134simulation, 149–151. See also <strong>Credit</strong>standard deviation, 86variableconfidence level, 138variance, 92Loss correlation, 145. See also <strong>Bond</strong>s; Obligorsdifferences, 121migration mode, 103–104, 111default correlation, relationship, 99–100<strong>in</strong>ferr<strong>in</strong>g, 98, 102Loss distribution, simulation, 123endnotes, 258–259questions, 138solutions, 248–249Loss given default (LGD), 75, 85, 93def<strong>in</strong>ition, 86Loss on default (LD), 85–87usage. See Quantity LDLow-default periods, 88Low-yield<strong>in</strong>g assets, 220m m matrix. See Probabilitym n matrix, 13, 181Macroeconomic factors, 107Mahadevan, Sivan, 260Manhattan Project, 124Mann, Christopher, 89, 258Manufactured-hous<strong>in</strong>g contracts, 26Marg<strong>in</strong>al credit risk contribution, 160–162Marketasset values, global database, 109capitalization. See Lehman Brothers; U.S. Treasurybondsdiscipl<strong>in</strong>e, 34price, 31size. See Relative market sizevalue. See Portfoliotransactions, 260yields, reference, 48Market risk, 26–27, 56, 83exposures, 61factors, 62, 252constra<strong>in</strong>ts, 196measures, 3, 198model, 61–65model<strong>in</strong>g, 51, 67questions, 65–66solutions, 243report. See Portfolioreport<strong>in</strong>g, 4sources, 61tail risk measures, 168Market value CDOscontrast. See Cash flowrat<strong>in</strong>g, 225–226Market-driven volatility, representation, 157Markov cha<strong>in</strong>s, 12–13. See also Discrete-timeMarkov cha<strong>in</strong>; Homogeneous Markovcha<strong>in</strong>Markov matrix, 17–19, 22, 239–240non-negative row, 17Markov process, 12Markowitz portfolio theory, 97Mark-to-marketloss, 67value. See <strong>Bond</strong>s; PortfolioMatrix. See Correlation; Diagonal matrix; Identitymatrix; Markov matrix; S<strong>in</strong>gular matrix;Square matrixdecomposition, 19diagonalization, 15eigenvalue, 15. See also Square matrixelements, 17, 193<strong>in</strong>verse, 14–15normalized eigenvectors. See Covariance


Index 269notation, 195product, 14–15properties. See Symmetric matrixtranspose, 14, 15Maturityquoted swap rates, 58test. See Weighted average maturity testMBS. See Mortgage-backed securitiesMcCauley, Robert, 44McNeil, Alexander, 259Mean, 238. See also Beta distribution; Distribution;Gamma distributionMean recovery rate, 92Mertonapproach. See Defaultframework, 112, 126modifications, 72underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gs, 143model, 128options theory framework, 68Metropolis, Nicholas, 124Mezzan<strong>in</strong>e notes, 212Mezzan<strong>in</strong>e tranches, 213Migrationmatrix. See Rat<strong>in</strong>g migrationmode, 89, 118, 122, 135, 148. See also <strong>Credit</strong> risk;Expected loss; Loss correlation; Portfoliocredit risk; Two-bond portfolio; Unexpectedlossusage, 137, 187–188, 203, 233probabilities, computation. See Jo<strong>in</strong>t migrationprobabilitiesMigration mode (PMM), 189portfolio, 190–191M<strong>in</strong>ima, exhibition, 182M<strong>in</strong>imum average rat<strong>in</strong>g test, 216M<strong>in</strong>imum recovery test, 216Mixture distributions, 141. See also Multivariatenormal mixture distributionsModel risk, 121Modified duration, 52, 234. See also <strong>Bond</strong>susage, 53Monte Carlo methods, 123–125Monte Carlo simulation, 123, 135convergence, 248methods, 127perform<strong>in</strong>g, 131techniques, 221, 226usage, 125–126Monte Carlo techniques, 258Moody’s Investors Service, 68, 228–229default, def<strong>in</strong>ition, 70evaluations, 222method. See Collateralized debt obligationstransactionrat<strong>in</strong>gs, 24, 234, 260contrast. See Standard & Poor’s Corporationrecovery rate, proxy<strong>in</strong>g, 75–76Morgan Stanley. See Tradable Custodial ReceiptsMorgan Stanley Capital International (MSCI),201–202Mortality rates, assumptions, 48Mortgage bondholders, 25Mortgage bonds, 25. See also Closed-end mortgagebonds; Open-end mortgage bondsissuers, 25types, 25Mortgage debt, 25Mortgage-backed securities (MBS), 26MSCI. See Morgan Stanley Capital InternationalMult<strong>in</strong>ormal distribution, 165Multistate credit event, 77Multivariate normal distribution, 140–143assumption. See Asset returnMultivariate normal mixture distributions, 140Multivariate t distribution, 143, 148, 164, 251assumptions, 175, 252. See also Asset returnMultivariate t-distributed random variablesn-dimensional sequence generation, 150usage, 250Multivariate t-distributed random vectors, 149, 154n n covariance matrix, eigenvalues, 19n n matrix, 14, 17, 181NAG. See Numerical Algorithms GroupNational Association of Securities Dealers (NASD),31–32n-bond portfolio, 97, 128–130n-dimensional t variate, 250NE. See Nom<strong>in</strong>al exposureNegative carry, 219Negative pledge provision, 25Net cumulative unrecognized actuarial ga<strong>in</strong>s/losses,48Nom<strong>in</strong>al amount, 195. See also <strong>Bond</strong>sNom<strong>in</strong>al exposure (NE), 56, 84–85. See also <strong>Bond</strong>s;Portfoliocalculations, 91–94default mode, 99loss variable, 96Nom<strong>in</strong>al value. See DefaultNonbank fund<strong>in</strong>g sources, 32Nondefaulted assets, 229Non<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade bonds, 70Non-<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade bonds, 24Non-<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade issuer, 74Non-<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade rat<strong>in</strong>g, 18Nonl<strong>in</strong>ear function, 53Nonl<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g, 181–182problem, 180, 182, 204, 254Non-negative eigenvalues, 181Nonperform<strong>in</strong>g loans, 33Non-Treasury component. See Long-term dollardenom<strong>in</strong>atedreservesNontrivial solutions, 15Nonzero values, 14Normal distribution, 8, 249. See also Multivariatenormal distributionfunction, 97motivation, 140–142Normal distribution assumption, relaxation, 139. Seealso Asset returnendnotes, 259questions, 154solutions, 249–250Normal random variables. See Uncorrelatedstandardized normal random variablesNormalized direction vectors, 240Normalized eigenvectors. See Covariance matrix;Symmetric matrixNormalized shift risk vector, 60Normalized vector, 60Normally distributed random variables, 72, 125uncorrelation, 12zero mean, 71Numerical Algorithms Group (NAG), 4Nyfeler, Mark, 259OAS. See Option-adjusted spreadObligation, face value, 68


270 INDEXObligors. See Investment-grade obligorasset returns, 246creditimprovement, 128rat<strong>in</strong>g, 17, 114, 146jo<strong>in</strong>t default, probability, 144loss correlation, 189number. See Portfoliopairs, 95default correlation, 144PD, 101rat<strong>in</strong>g, 162migrations, model<strong>in</strong>g, 12recovery rate, 100, 138, 254OC. See OvercollateralizationO’Connor, Gerard, 223, 224Off-diagonal elements, 14Off-the-run securities, 30One-notch rat<strong>in</strong>g downgrade, 70Open-end mortgage bonds, 25Open-ended assets, 25Open-ended issues, 25Operat<strong>in</strong>g costs, 48Optimal portfolio composition, 188–191, 203risk profile, 188Optimization. See Portfolio optimizationmethods, 180–182techniques. See Portfolio selectionOptimization problems, 187–188constra<strong>in</strong>ts, 194functions, 196setup, 185–187design variable, 188difficulties, 182–183Option-adjusted convexity, 55Option-adjusted duration, 55Option-adjusted risk measures, 55Option-adjusted spread (OAS), 54Optionsdelta, 54gamma, 54Orig<strong>in</strong>ation risk, 219OTC. See Over-the-counterOu, Sharon, 258Outperformance, 158, 170. See also Benchmark; U.S.TreasuriesOutstand<strong>in</strong>g debt, payment obligations, 27Overcollateralization (OC) tests, 217–218, 229Over-the-counter (OTC)market, 23trades, 32Par value. See <strong>Bond</strong>s; Collateral poolPar yield curve, 57Par-build<strong>in</strong>g, 236, 255Parent company, bankruptcy, 75PCA. See Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysisPD. See Probability of defaultPDM. See Default modePension assets, 47proportion. See Fixed-<strong>in</strong>come securitiesPension expense/obligations,measurement, 48Pension funds, 47–50account<strong>in</strong>g rules, 50actuarial liabilities, 47–48deficit/surplus, 48implications, 49–50plan sponsors, 40surplus, volatilities, 49Pension liabilities, 47valuation, discount rate usage, 49Performance. See Historical performancemonthly reports, 133Performance attribution, 155, 170–175endnotes, 259model, 156style factors, 173questions, 175–176report, purpose, 171solutions, 250–253style factor, 172Perform<strong>in</strong>g assets, 217Physical property, 240Picone, Domenico, 261Plan assets, fair value measurement, 48Pledge provision. See Negative pledge provisionPledged property, 25PMM. See Migration modePool. See Collateral poolPortfolio. See Active portfolio; Rebalanced portfoliosaggregates, 56–57base currency, 192, 197benchmark, relative credit risk, 158composition, 231–233. See also Optimal portfoliocompositionrobustness, 191construction, 183–191problem, 205credit loss, distribution, 126, 134shape, 158default mode. See Two-bond portfoliodownside risk, 163effective convexity, 57<strong>in</strong>jections/withdrawal, 192level, 96loss correlation, 187loss distribution, 96simulation, 135managementskills, 229style, 28, 30–31managers, 252. See also <strong>Corporate</strong> portfoliomanagersperformance, 65marketrisk report, 168–170value, 192mark-to-market value, 133, 136nom<strong>in</strong>al exposure, 158, 186obligors, number, 131performance, analysis, 156quantification, subjectivity, 101–102rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g, 4, 191–198illustration, 197–198problem, 192, 205returns, standard deviation, 98risk, management, 51risk-adjusted return, 195turnover, 254size, 192unexpected loss, aggregation, 103–104yield, constra<strong>in</strong>t function, 196Portfolio credit risk, 3, 95, 116–117, 142–149aggregation, 122, 246computation, 3, 125default mode, 143–145endnotes, 258illustration, 118–121migration mode, 145–149


Index 271quantification, 95–98quantities. See Interestquestions, 121–122report, 162–167solutions, 246–248Portfolio optimization, 177endnotes, 260questions, 204–205solutions, 253–254techniques, 4Portfolio selectionconceptual framework. See Efficient portfolioselectionoptimization techniques, illustration, 199–204problems, 181, 186, 199, 204–205techniques, 178–180quantitative approach, benefits, 179–180Positive-def<strong>in</strong>ite matrix, 16Positive-semidef<strong>in</strong>ite matrix, 181Postemployment benefit obligation, discount<strong>in</strong>g, 48Prepayment risk, 208, 220Press, Wiliam, 259Price changesapproximation, 53estimation, 89–90Price compression, 54Price differentials, 89Price movements, 219Price risk, 89measure, 57Price-yield relationships. See <strong>Bond</strong>scurvature, 53Pric<strong>in</strong>g anomalies, 31–32Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component analysis (PCA), 19–21, 243Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component decomposition, 58Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal component vectors, 59Pr<strong>in</strong>cipal componentscomputation, 20random variables, 21Prior mortgage bonds, 25Pro rata pr<strong>in</strong>cipal paydown mechanism, 216Probabilitydensity function, 8–9, 142. See also Uniformlydistributed random variabledeterm<strong>in</strong>ation. See <strong>Credit</strong>distributions, 8–10. See also Jo<strong>in</strong>t probabilitydistributionscharacteristics, 5–8function, 6estimates. See Default<strong>in</strong>dependence. See Transitionmassestimation, 132function, 6theory, 2, 5–13transition matrix (m m matrix), 13vector, 18Probability of default (PD), 67–75, 94, 144assessment, 74determ<strong>in</strong>ation, 71empirical approach, 68–71structural approach, comparison, 74Merton approach, 71–73usage, 84. See also Historical PDvalues, 80estimation (KMV Corporation), 88Production overcapacity, 33Programm<strong>in</strong>g. See L<strong>in</strong>ear programm<strong>in</strong>g; Nonl<strong>in</strong>earprogramm<strong>in</strong>g; Quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>gProject f<strong>in</strong>ance, 209Project unit credit method, usage, 48Projected unit credit method, 48Protection seller, 210Public utilities, 23, 76Putable bond, 55Quadratic function, 254Quadratic programm<strong>in</strong>g, 181problem, 180, 182, 187solv<strong>in</strong>g, 188Quality tests. See CollateralQuantitative models, 2Quantity LD, usage, 86Quoted price, 52Quoted swap rates. See MaturityRamaswamy, Srichander, 199–200, 259, 260Ramp-up risk, 219Random numbers, simulation, 248Random outcomes, sequence properties (study), 12Random variable, 5–7, 84. See also Bernoulli randomvariable; Discrete zero-one random variable;Uncorrelated standardized normal randomvariablesactual value, 7covariance, 11, 20degrees of freedom. See Chi-square-distributedrandom variableexpected value, def<strong>in</strong>ition, 7<strong>in</strong>dependence, 11probability density function. See Uniformlydistributed random variablesequence, 150generation. See Multivariate t-distributedrandom variablestime, 13uncorrelation, 12. See also Normally distributedrandom variablesvalues, 13variance, 20, 58, 86sum, 20variance-covariance structure, 19Random variate, simulation, 250Random vector. See Multivariate t-distributedrandom vectors; Zero-mean random vectorsequence, generation, 127Rat<strong>in</strong>g. See Non-<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade rat<strong>in</strong>goutlooks, 74test. See M<strong>in</strong>imum average rat<strong>in</strong>g testtransition matrix, 17–19, 22, 94upgrades/downgrades, relative frequencies, 78Rat<strong>in</strong>g migration, 68, 77–81framework, 91matrix, 18–19model<strong>in</strong>g. See ObligorsReal earn<strong>in</strong>gs, growth rate, 49Real estate prices, impact, 32Rebalanced portfolios, 198Rebalanc<strong>in</strong>g. See Portfoliotrades, identification, 194–197Receivables, 25, 210. See also <strong>Credit</strong> card receivablesRecession, 88. See also Economic recessionRecovery rate (RR), 68, 75–77. See also Mean recoveryrate; Obligors; Weighted average recovery rateassumption, 247average, 84, 88differences, 76<strong>in</strong>dependence, 145process, 99, 238. See also Defaulted bondsvolatility, 22


272 INDEXRecovery rate (cont<strong>in</strong>ued)proxy<strong>in</strong>g. See Moody’s Investors Servicestandard deviation, 77, 91time dimension, 76values, 200Recovery test. See M<strong>in</strong>imum recovery testRecovery values, simulation, 10Reduced-form models, 87, 94, 245Regime-switch<strong>in</strong>g model, 88Registered bonds, 24Regulatory capital, 208Re<strong>in</strong>vestment period, 214Re<strong>in</strong>vestment risk, 219–220Relative credit risk, 164measures, 156–160. See also Portfolioderivation, 157Relative CrVaR, 158measure, 160Relative ESR, 158computation, 168Relative market size, 35–37Relative riskcapture, 190level, 169quantification, 157Relative weight vector, 195Remarks, 26Repayments, schedule, 214Reserveslevel. See Foreign currency reservesmanagers, 242challenges, 50job rotation, 45opportunity costs, 43portfolio, 45diversification benefits, 46Residual returns, 174Resti, Andrea, 258Retirement benefits, provid<strong>in</strong>g, 48Returns. See Stock pricesattribution model, 173correlation, estimation. See Asset return correlationcovariance matrix. See Security returnsdistribution, computation, 8standard deviation, 81target, 43<strong>Risk</strong>. See Expected shortfall risk; Issuer specific riskanalysis, 253. See also Structured credit portfoliodrill-down capability, 168assessment. See F<strong>in</strong>ancial securities<strong>in</strong>feriority, 33attributes, identification, 178capture, 165characteristics, 231–233concentrations, reduction, 214elim<strong>in</strong>ation, 177exposure, 171. See also <strong>Corporate</strong> bond portfoliofactors, 59, 63, 156–157, 184. See also Benchmark;Implied yield volatility risk factormodel<strong>in</strong>g, 251sensitivity, 185shift, 60guidel<strong>in</strong>es, 169–170management, 1measurement, 155measures, 54–55. See also Market risk; Tail riskmeasuresabsence, 1model, 65, 162estimation, 156model<strong>in</strong>g. See <strong>Credit</strong> risk model<strong>in</strong>gexercise, 106parameters duration/convexity, 129premium, 46profile, 232quantification, 97. See also <strong>Corporate</strong> bondportfolioreduction, 203–204report, 161drill-down capability, 155scenario, 64sensitivity, 169sources, 168. See also Collateralized debtobligationsvector. See Normalized shift risk vector<strong>Risk</strong> report<strong>in</strong>g, 155. See also Economic contractionsendnotes, 259questions, 175–176solutions, 250–253<strong>Risk</strong>-adjusted return. See Portfolio<strong>Risk</strong>-free bond returns, 105<strong>Risk</strong>-free debt components, 106<strong>Risk</strong>-free returns, 39<strong>Risk</strong>-return characteristics, 179. See alsoBenchmark<strong>Risk</strong>-return measures, 38<strong>Risk</strong>-return tradeoffs, 180RR. See Recovery rateRussia, default (1998), 33Salaries, progression, 48Sampl<strong>in</strong>g. See Importance sampl<strong>in</strong>gScalar quantity, 15Scale parameter (beta), 8–9Scenario analysis. See <strong>Credit</strong>-event-driven scenarioanalysisScenario default rates (SDRs), 226–228. See alsoCollateral portfolioestimates, 228Schwartz, David, 260SDRs. See Scenario default ratesSecond central moment, 7Second mortgage bonds, 25Secondary markets, liquidity (absence), 34Secured bonds, 24issuance, 35–36Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC),registration, 32Securityprices, changes, 51returns, covariance matrix, 16Sell transactionsidentification, 192–194list, 194Senior CDO tranches, 236Senior debt tranches, 212Senior note, issuance, 212Senior unsecured bonds, 24–25, 94mean recovery rate, 77Senior unsecured debt, 118Senior unsecured f<strong>in</strong>ancial obligations, honor<strong>in</strong>g, 69Seniority. See DebtService cost, 48Shahabudd<strong>in</strong>, Perwez, 259Shape parameter (alpha), 8–9Sharpe, William, 37, 257ratios, 40Shift, 58risk vector. See Normalized shift risk vectorsensitivity, 169


Index 273Short-dated f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>struments, portfolio, 41Shortfall risk. See Expected shortfall riskShort-term foreign debt, 42Siegel, Jay, 258Simulated loss data, usage, 130, 135–137Simulationefficiency, improvement, 131performance, 233runs, 124number, 131, 133S<strong>in</strong>gular matrix, 15Sironi, Andrea, 258Six-factor market risk model, estimate, 64Skewness. See Distributiondef<strong>in</strong>ition, 7Sobel, Milton, 259Sovereign credit rat<strong>in</strong>gs, determ<strong>in</strong>ation, 42Special-purpose vehicle (SPV), 26, 210. See alsoBankruptcy-remote SPVcreation, 212Spread. See Option-adjusted spreadSPV. See Special-purpose vehicleSquare matrix, 13eigenvalues, 15Standard & Poor’s Corporation, 68500 <strong>in</strong>dex returns, 40<strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate bond returns,correlation coefficient, 39500 stock <strong>in</strong>dex, 37, 38adjustment factors, details, 228<strong>in</strong>dustry classifications, 227method. See Collateralized debt obligationstransactionMoody’s rat<strong>in</strong>gs, contrast, 89rat<strong>in</strong>g, 24Standard deviation, 7, 8. See also <strong>Credit</strong> loss; Returnscomputation, 129Static pool, 68. See also IssuersSte<strong>in</strong>, Roger, 260Stochastic processes, 12–13. See also Cont<strong>in</strong>uous-timestochastic process; Discrete-state stochasticprocess; Discrete-time stochastic processstudy, 5Stock prices, returns, 7Strike price, 54, 73Structural credit enhancement, 212Structural factors, 88Structural models, 87Merton. See DebtStructural protections, 215–218Structured credit portfolio, risk analysis, 231–232Structured credit products, 206endnotes, 260–261implied credit rat<strong>in</strong>g, 235questions, 236solutions, 255–256Student t distribution, 140–144function, 145Subord<strong>in</strong>ated CDO debt tranches, 212Subord<strong>in</strong>ation, 216Supranational <strong>in</strong>stitutions, 171Surplus risk, 50, 242Swap curve, 63. See also Euro swap curves; U.S.dollar swap curveSwap rates, changes, 63Symmetric matrix, 13normalized eigenvectors, 16properties, 15–16Synthetic CDOs, contrast. See Cash CDOsSystematic risks, 61factors, 179replication, 178Systemic risks, 32reduction, 34t distribution, 142. See also Bivariate t distribution;Multivariate t distribution; Student t distributiont probability computation, C programimplementation. See Bivariate t probabilitycomputationTail dependence, 140Tail probability, 144exam<strong>in</strong>ation, 134Tail risk measures, 132–135, 151. See also Marketriskusage, 207Tail risk statistics, 246Targeted Return Index Securities (Tra<strong>in</strong>s) (LehmanBrothers), 206, 230Taylor series expansion, first-order return, 53Tesher, David, 260Teukolsky, Saul, 259Time series data, 157Top-tier corporates, 34Total asset return correlation, 111Total credit loss. See Two-bond portfolioTotal variance, proportion, 21TRA. See TransportationTRACE. See Trade Report<strong>in</strong>g and Compliance Eng<strong>in</strong>eTracers. See Tradable Custodial ReceiptsTrack<strong>in</strong>g error, 66, 155, 168, 254. See also Ex antetrack<strong>in</strong>g errors; Historical track<strong>in</strong>g errorsm<strong>in</strong>imization, 178Tradable Custodial Receipts (tracers) (MorganStanley), 206, 230–231, 256, 261exam<strong>in</strong>ation, 233features, 231portfolio composition, 231series, 235ten-year, 232Trade Report<strong>in</strong>g and Compliance Eng<strong>in</strong>e (TRACE), 32TRACE-eligible security, 32Tradeable corporate bond baskets, 4Trad<strong>in</strong>g costs. See <strong>Corporate</strong> bondsTra<strong>in</strong>s. See Targeted Return Index SecuritiesTranches, 212. See also Collateralized debtobligations; EquitiesTransactionscosts, 182<strong>in</strong>crease, 23reduction, 211identification. See Sell transactionsvolumes, 183Transformation algorithm, 125Transitionmatrix. See Probability; Rat<strong>in</strong>gprobability. See Historical transition probabilityestimation, 78<strong>in</strong>dependence, 13Transportation (TRA), 110companies, 23Transpose. See MatrixTrust bonds. See CollateralTrustees, 214–215Turnover, 193constra<strong>in</strong>t, 182, 197size. See PortfolioTwist, 58component, 62risk factor, 60


274 INDEXTwo-bond portfoliodefault mode, 102–104example, 122expected loss, 148<strong>in</strong>terest, credit risk parameters, 117migration mode, 117–118total credit loss, 130unexpected loss, 116, 148<strong>in</strong>crease, 98Two-obligor portfolio, 96–97UL. See Unexpected lossULC. See Unexpected loss contributionULp. See Unexpected portfolio lossUncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, representation, 10Uncorrelated standardized normal randomvariables, 16Underperformance, 159, 170. See also Benchmarklevel, 158magnitude, 156, 168probability, 251risk, 164Underwrit<strong>in</strong>g skills. See <strong>Credit</strong>Unexpected loss contribution (ULC), 161–162Unexpected loss (UL), 96–100. See also Two-bondportfoliocomputation, 130–131illustration, 92–94default mode, 86–88denotation, 117<strong>in</strong>crease. See Two-bond portfoliomigration mode, 91–92m<strong>in</strong>imization. See Active portfoliousage, 249Unexpected portfolio loss (ULp), 96–97, 103, 130,145Uniform distribution, 10Uniformly distributed random variable, probabilitydensity function, 10Unit vectors, 19Unsecured bonds, 24. See also Senior unsecuredbondssecurity, 25Unsecured debt. See Senior unsecured debtUnsecuritized corporate bonds, 26U.S. dollar curve, 64–65U.S. dollar swap curve, 60dynamics, 64U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated corporate bonds, 36U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated fixed-<strong>in</strong>comeassets, 37U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporatebonds, 37U.S. dollar-denom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong>vestment-grade corporate<strong>in</strong>dex, 38U.S. Treasuries, 27corporate bonds, outperformance, 46foreign credit spread, 42long-term yield enhancement, 46market capitalization, 36–37performance, 37yield spread, 28U.S. Treasury bonds, market capitalization, 28U.S. Treasury portfolios, performance, 47U.S. Treasury returns, correlation. See Investmentgradecorporate bondsUtilities (UTL), 25, 111, 173sector, subclassifications, 111Valuation price, 31Value at risk (VaR). See Conditional VaR; <strong>Credit</strong>value at riskcalculations, 7computation, 8VandeCastle, Karen, 258Variables, number. See Discrete probability treeVariance, 8, 238. See also Bernoulli random variable;Beta distribution; Distribution; Gammadistribution; Lossproportion. See Total varianceVariance-covariance structure. See Random variableVectors, 15. See also Direction vectors; Eigenvectors;Normalized vector; Probability; Unit vectors2-norm, 14norm, 14properties, 14sequence, generation. See Random vectorVehicle-leas<strong>in</strong>g firms, 25Vetterl<strong>in</strong>g, William, 259von Neumann, John, 124WAC. See Weighted average couponWARF. See Weighted average rat<strong>in</strong>g factorWeight vector. See Relative weight vectorWeighted average coupon (WAC), 218Weighted average maturity test, 217Weighted average rat<strong>in</strong>g factor (WARF), 223–224, 235Weighted average recovery rate, 216Worst-case loss scenario, 83–84, 129Worst-case scenario, 133Yamai, Yasuhiro, 259Yield. See Effective yieldchanges, 57, 62covariance matrix, 58differentials, 31enhancement. See U.S. Treasuriespickup, 24reference. See Marketspread. See Fixed yield spreadimpact, 172volatility risk factor. See Implied yield volatilityYield curve, 52, 245. See also Par yield curveconstruction, 31dynamics, 57–60, 66empirical model<strong>in</strong>g, 19exposures, 253flatten<strong>in</strong>g/steepen<strong>in</strong>g, 59risk, model<strong>in</strong>g, 59shape, changes, 57shift, 243strategies, 30Yield to maturity, 52, 243change, 53Yoshiba, Tosh<strong>in</strong>ao, 259Young, Edward, 258Young, Robert, 258Zeng, B<strong>in</strong>, 258Zero-coupon bonds, issu<strong>in</strong>g, 72Zero-mean random vector, 16Zero-one random variable. See Discrete zero-onerandom variableZhang, J<strong>in</strong>g, 258z-thresholds, 112–114computation, 122, 145values, 122, 128, 248

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!