The Politics of Land Grabbing in Guatemala - Contested Global ...
The Politics of Land Grabbing in Guatemala - Contested Global ...
The Politics of Land Grabbing in Guatemala - Contested Global ...
Create successful ePaper yourself
Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.
<strong>The</strong> <strong>Politics</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Grabb<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>By: Alberto Alonso-FradejasPaper presented at theInternational Conference on<strong>Global</strong> <strong>Land</strong><strong>Grabb<strong>in</strong>g</strong> IIOctober 17‐19, 2012Organized by the <strong>Land</strong> Deals<strong>Politics</strong> Initiative (LDPI)and hosted by the Department<strong>of</strong> Development Sociology atCornell University, Ithaca, NY.
<strong>The</strong> <strong>Politics</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Control <strong>Grabb<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>Alberto Alonso-Fradejas 1Prepared for delivery on panel 5: “<strong>The</strong> <strong>Politics</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Deals: Regional Perspectives” at theInternational Conference on <strong>Global</strong> <strong>Land</strong> <strong>Grabb<strong>in</strong>g</strong> II, Cornell University, Ithaca, USA, 17-19October 2012.AbstractThis essay discusses land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g by sugarcane and oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses as ameans and an effect <strong>of</strong> a new extractivist political economy orchestrated from the oligarchic,yet transnationalized, post-colonial power <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>. This political economy is anchoredand steered from a dist<strong>in</strong>ctive government rationality delegitimiz<strong>in</strong>g non-complianteconomic, ecologic cultural and political practices. Under this rationale, different land controlgrabb<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms result <strong>in</strong> different directions <strong>of</strong> change <strong>in</strong> land use, property relations,and labor regimes, which reassign control over local land-based wealth. On the whole, thepolitics <strong>of</strong> land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g are pr<strong>of</strong>oundly shaped by both, entic<strong>in</strong>g and coercivedom<strong>in</strong>ant government tactics, as well as by socially differentiated perceptions <strong>of</strong> the way andextent to which subsistence security is violated. Placed-based, everyday practices <strong>of</strong>resistance <strong>in</strong>tertw<strong>in</strong>e with advocacy politics <strong>in</strong> the economic, ecologic, cultural and politicaldoma<strong>in</strong>s to advance a different life project. Indigenous people from different classes <strong>of</strong> labor,genders, and generations mobilize around a collective ethnic- and class-based identity. Fromthis non-unproblematic mobiliz<strong>in</strong>g discourse, struggles to defend access to and control overterritorial land resources are embedded <strong>in</strong> the wider claim to govern land resources andpopulations under a different, non-extractivist rationale. Local <strong>in</strong>digenous groups andgrassroots organizations engage with militant rural social movements to gather support, andaugment the political impact <strong>of</strong> their struggle beyond the local fronts. Concomitantly, theirplace-based resistances allow for the relocalization and base-amplification <strong>of</strong> militant ruralsocial movements, while open<strong>in</strong>g possibilities for the latter to develop an <strong>in</strong>tersectionalmobiliz<strong>in</strong>g discourse and a more comprehensive claim for different life projects.Keywords: <strong>Guatemala</strong>, land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g, extractivist political economy, government rationality,politics, rural social differentiation, rural social movements.1 PhD researcher at the International Institute <strong>of</strong> Social Studies (fradejas@iss.nl) I am most grateful for the supportreceived for this work from the <strong>Land</strong> Deal <strong>Politics</strong> Initiative (LDPI).1
IntroductionAgricultural and other ‘land-produced and land-based resources’ (here<strong>in</strong>after ‘land resources’)are outstand<strong>in</strong>gly and dist<strong>in</strong>ctively back <strong>in</strong> the world politico-economic context <strong>of</strong> convergentf<strong>in</strong>ancial, energy, food and environmental crises. Crisis- and resource scarcity-related discourseslaid a fertile ground for food, feedstocks, agr<strong>of</strong>uels, timber, m<strong>in</strong>erals, oil and biomass complexesto (re)emerge and/or ga<strong>in</strong> momentum as “global hubs <strong>of</strong> capital accumulation” (Borras et al.2012) to serve the needs <strong>of</strong> “a (m<strong>in</strong>ority) global class <strong>of</strong> consumers distributed across an<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly multi-centric global food [and other agro-commodities] system” (McMichael2012:5). Demand from these global hubs <strong>of</strong> capital accumulation has prompted, unevenly thoughacross North and South, rural and urban milieus, a wide range <strong>of</strong> contentious corporate landresources deals. <strong>The</strong>se deals, which are commonly referred to as ‘land grabs’ or ‘large-scale land<strong>in</strong>vestments’, depend<strong>in</strong>g on the ‘anti’ or ‘pro’/‘pro-but’ political standpo<strong>in</strong>ts, have led multipleagents across and with<strong>in</strong> the state, overseas development agencies, academy, corporations,NGOs, social movements and (less <strong>of</strong>ten) concerned local populations to engage <strong>in</strong> vivid debatesabout the impacts, risks and opportunities brought about by these corporate land resources deals.In engag<strong>in</strong>g with such debates, this article reflects on the political dynamics <strong>of</strong> contemporaryagrarian change <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> on the basis <strong>of</strong> results from research conducted between 2006 and2011 <strong>in</strong> particular geographical and historical conjunctures (Hart, 2002: 818) where land grabsby sugarcane and oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses have been and are under way. Research <strong>in</strong> thesemilieus tried to overcome the analytical constra<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> what Borras et al. (2012) consider both‘narrow’ and ‘too broad’ def<strong>in</strong>itions <strong>of</strong> land grabb<strong>in</strong>g. From the former po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>of</strong> view, land grabsare just understood as large-scale land acquisitions <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g foreign governments andunderm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g food security <strong>of</strong> a country. From the later one, all k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> land transactions are<strong>in</strong>cluded, blurr<strong>in</strong>g then land resources grabs with<strong>in</strong> small- and medium-scale everyday forms <strong>of</strong>dispossession by socio-economic differentiation (Borras et al., 2012: 847, 851). <strong>The</strong>refore, wewill build here on Borras et al.’s understand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> land grabb<strong>in</strong>g as “captur<strong>in</strong>g control <strong>of</strong>relatively vast tracts <strong>of</strong> land and other natural resources through a variety <strong>of</strong> mechanisms that<strong>in</strong>volve large-scale capital that <strong>of</strong>ten shifts resource use orientation <strong>in</strong>to extractivecharacter, whether for <strong>in</strong>ternational or domestic purposes, as capital’s response to theconvergence <strong>of</strong> food, energy and f<strong>in</strong>ancial crises, climate change mitigation imperatives, anddemands for resources from newer hubs <strong>of</strong> global capital” (2012:851, stress added).Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, we will explore contemporary mechanisms for land grabb<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> from a‘control’ perspective, consider<strong>in</strong>g the ‘scale <strong>of</strong> capital’ <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the deals, and their‘extractive’ rationale. This take has, then, three analytical implications. First, we view themechanisms for grabb<strong>in</strong>g ‘control’ over land resources as “practices that fix or consolidate forms<strong>of</strong> access and exclusion for some time” (Peluso and Lund 2011:668). As we will further argue,these practices are highly determ<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> by the ‘bundle <strong>of</strong> powers’ enabl<strong>in</strong>g (orconstra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g) the abilities <strong>of</strong> different agents to ga<strong>in</strong>, ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> and control their access to landresources beyond legally-sanctioned property rights (Ribot and Peluso 2003). Second, we are notas much <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> account<strong>in</strong>g for land grabs on physical terms as we are <strong>in</strong> shift<strong>in</strong>g controlover land-based wealth. Thus, we will focus more on the scale and character <strong>of</strong> the capital<strong>in</strong>volved than <strong>in</strong> the number <strong>of</strong> control-grabbed hectares (Borras et al. 2012:851). Third, the2
change <strong>of</strong> resource use orientation <strong>in</strong>to extractive character characterizes most <strong>of</strong> the multipleland resources control grabs converg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> 2 . This is also the case <strong>of</strong> thepredom<strong>in</strong>antly large-scale, agro<strong>in</strong>dustrial sugarcane and oil palm plantations discussed here. Aswe will show, forest and peasant-farmed lands are put under <strong>in</strong>tensive and extensive production<strong>of</strong> sugarcane and especially <strong>of</strong> oil palm. <strong>The</strong>se are both ‘flex-crops’ subject to “multiple uses(food, feed, fuel, <strong>in</strong>dustrial material) that can be easily and flexibly <strong>in</strong>ter-changed” (Borras et al.2012:851). Thus, these flex-crops serve the needs for raw materials (or relatively little<strong>in</strong>dustrialized <strong>in</strong>puts) <strong>of</strong> several <strong>of</strong> the aforementioned global hubs <strong>of</strong> capital accumulation. It isunder this rationale, then, that land-based wealth is extracted from the produc<strong>in</strong>g territory andredirected towards distant national and <strong>in</strong>ternational capital owners.Nonetheless, land control grabs by the sugarcane and oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses are far from be<strong>in</strong>gjust an <strong>in</strong>cidental outcome <strong>of</strong> the overarch<strong>in</strong>g determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> these global hubs <strong>of</strong> capitalaccumulation over the <strong>Guatemala</strong>n countryside. Arguably, land control grabs are more a meansand an effect <strong>of</strong> a new extractivist political economy carefully orchestrated from the very core <strong>of</strong>the post-colonial oligarchy. <strong>The</strong> “newness” <strong>of</strong> this extractivist political economy, emerg<strong>in</strong>g fromthe mid-2000s onwards, lies <strong>in</strong> two dist<strong>in</strong>ctive and <strong>in</strong>tertw<strong>in</strong>ed features. On the one side, it isbe<strong>in</strong>g conceived and unfolded through complementary ‘political’ and ‘economic’ logics <strong>of</strong>power <strong>in</strong> capitalism (see Arrighi 1994, Harvey 2003, 2005 and Wood 2003) <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> throughthe subjugation <strong>of</strong> one <strong>of</strong> these logics to the other, as <strong>in</strong> previous historical junctures. On theother side, the new extractivist political economy is anchored and steered from a particular,dom<strong>in</strong>ant government rationality delegitimiz<strong>in</strong>g non-compliant/non-functional economic,political, ecologic and cultural practices. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, the cultural and subjective doma<strong>in</strong>s becomethe battlefield <strong>of</strong> dispute <strong>of</strong> the symbolic power underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g ‘non-aligned’ agro-ecologicalknowledge and govern<strong>in</strong>g practices (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g customs) <strong>of</strong> populations <strong>in</strong> target territories. It is<strong>in</strong> this way that a functional but socially legitimate vision <strong>of</strong> the world is produced an imposed(Bourdieu, 1986: 21).Thus, our approach to the politics <strong>of</strong> land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g aims at br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g together “discoursesand struggles around culture (<strong>of</strong>ten the focus <strong>of</strong> ethnic, gender and other movements foridentity); environment (the <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>of</strong> environmental justice movements); and diverse economies(the concern <strong>of</strong> social and economic justice movements)” (Escobar, 2008: 15). With<strong>in</strong> thisrelational framework, we will first give some critical <strong>in</strong>sights on the extractivist politicaleconomy <strong>of</strong> the sugarcane- and oil palm-related land control grabs. In so do<strong>in</strong>g, we will deal withBernste<strong>in</strong>’s critical agrarian political economy questions: “who owns what? who does what? whogets what? what do they do with it?” (2010a:22), consider<strong>in</strong>g also “what do they do to eachother? <strong>in</strong> order to capture the relational and political side <strong>of</strong> property and labor regimes, laborprocesses and structures <strong>of</strong> accumulation” (White and Dasgupta 2010:600). By stress<strong>in</strong>g that“the emergence <strong>of</strong> specific labor regimes is not <strong>in</strong>evitable but the product <strong>of</strong> politics”(White et al. 2012: 622) we will understand the labor regimes as “specific methods <strong>of</strong> mobiliz<strong>in</strong>glabor and organiz<strong>in</strong>g it <strong>in</strong> production, and their particular social, economic and politicalconditions” (Bernste<strong>in</strong>, 1988, <strong>in</strong> White et al., 2012: 622).2 In the fields <strong>of</strong> agriculture, tourism, m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, oil extraction, economic and logistical corridors, logg<strong>in</strong>g, carbontrad<strong>in</strong>g, cattle ranch<strong>in</strong>g and, not unimportantly, to wash money from drug-traffick<strong>in</strong>g3
Further, we will also discuss how this new extractivist political economy from the mid-2000sonwards is <strong>in</strong> fact enabled by and enabl<strong>in</strong>g dist<strong>in</strong>ctive changes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Guatemala</strong>n state’s version<strong>of</strong> a neoliberal ‘government rationality’. With this <strong>in</strong>tention, we build on Foucault’s broaddef<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>of</strong> ‘government’ as the ‘conduct <strong>of</strong> conducts’, that is, as “a form <strong>of</strong> activity aim<strong>in</strong>g toshape, guide or affect the conduct <strong>of</strong> some person or [group <strong>of</strong>] persons” (Gordon, 1991: 2) 3 .However, <strong>in</strong> order to avoid determ<strong>in</strong>istic views <strong>of</strong> power as:“Shap<strong>in</strong>g completely other’s conduct (as slavery, for <strong>in</strong>stance), Foucault def<strong>in</strong>ed power as‘actions on others’ actions’, that is, it presupposes rather than annuls their capacity as agents.[Hence] although power is an omnipresent dimension <strong>in</strong> human relations, power <strong>in</strong> a societyis never a fixed and closed regime, but rather and endless and open strategic game [subject,therefore, to] its ‘strategic reversibility’, or the ways <strong>in</strong> which the terms <strong>of</strong> governmentalpractice can be turned around <strong>in</strong>to focuses <strong>of</strong> resistance, or the way the history <strong>of</strong> governmentas the ‘conduct <strong>of</strong> conduct’ is <strong>in</strong>terwoven with the history <strong>of</strong> dissent<strong>in</strong>g counter-conducts”(Foucault, 1978 <strong>in</strong> Gordon, 1991: 5).Government as practice entails, then, “the right manner <strong>of</strong> dispos<strong>in</strong>g th<strong>in</strong>gs so as to lead […] toan end which is ‘convenient’ for each <strong>of</strong> the th<strong>in</strong>gs that are to be governed, [and thus], to aplurality <strong>of</strong> specific aims” (Foucault, 1991: 95, stress added). ‘Th<strong>in</strong>gs’ are rightly disposed, fromthis standpo<strong>in</strong>t <strong>of</strong> government as practice, through the employment <strong>of</strong> “tactics rather than laws,and even [through the use <strong>of</strong>] laws themselves as tactics-to arrange th<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> such a way, througha certa<strong>in</strong> number <strong>of</strong> means, that such and such ends may be achieved” (ibid, stressed added).Indeed, we will argue how both coercive and entic<strong>in</strong>g means <strong>in</strong>form the dom<strong>in</strong>ant governmentalrationality tactics aimed at controll<strong>in</strong>g and rul<strong>in</strong>g over land resources and population (labor) notonly materially, but also symbolically. A ‘rationality <strong>of</strong> government’ will entail, accord<strong>in</strong>gly, “away or system <strong>of</strong> th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g about the nature <strong>of</strong> the practice <strong>of</strong> government (who can govern; whatgovern<strong>in</strong>g is; what or who is governed), capable <strong>of</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g some form <strong>of</strong> that activity th<strong>in</strong>kableand practicable both to its practitioners and to those upon whom it is practiced” (Gordon,1991:3).From our particular analytical take on politics it is worth stress<strong>in</strong>g that Foucault applied thenotion <strong>of</strong> ‘government’ to the govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the self and others <strong>in</strong> different doma<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> the<strong>in</strong>dividual and social life, and not only to government as exclusive practice <strong>of</strong> the state. Thus,“government as an activity could concern the relation between self and self, private <strong>in</strong>terpersonalrelations <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g some form <strong>of</strong> control or guidance, relations with<strong>in</strong> social <strong>in</strong>stitutions andcommunities and, f<strong>in</strong>ally, relations concerned with the exercise <strong>of</strong> political sovereignty” (Gordon1991:2). This is a crucial dist<strong>in</strong>ction because, acknowledg<strong>in</strong>g the tensions, varieties and disputeswith<strong>in</strong> each <strong>of</strong> them, we will be deal<strong>in</strong>g here with basically two broad, ideal-type and so faroppos<strong>in</strong>g (even if still mutually constitutive) government practices and rationales. <strong>The</strong>re is, onthe one side, a dom<strong>in</strong>ant rationale <strong>of</strong> govern<strong>in</strong>g populations and resources under a new3 Note that we are engag<strong>in</strong>g here with Foucault’s notion on the concept <strong>of</strong> (modern) ‘government’ withoutnecessarily extrapolat<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Guatemala</strong>n case his geographically and historically situated def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>of</strong> the ‘liberalgovernment rationality’, emerg<strong>in</strong>g from the eighteenth century onwards <strong>in</strong> western Europe. In fact, we build moreon a ‘Foucaultian’ than <strong>in</strong> a ‘Foucaultist’ analytical take on govern<strong>in</strong>g population and (land) resources.4
<strong>The</strong> agribus<strong>in</strong>esses’ <strong>in</strong>vestment strategy with<strong>in</strong> the new extractivist politicaleconomy and government rationality248,000 and 102,000 hectares <strong>of</strong> sugarcane and oil palm were harvested <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> <strong>in</strong> 2011and 2010. 4 This may seem small, but it represents the potential to cover a large portion <strong>of</strong> thecountryside. <strong>Guatemala</strong>n government considers over a million hectares suitable for sugarcaneand oil palm production - 20% and 37% respectively <strong>of</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’s arable land. Exportrevenues from sugar and crude palm oil <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> 108% and 587% respectively between 2000and 2010. Ethanol export-revenues grew 67% between 2006 and 2010.<strong>The</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> this export boom are concentrated <strong>in</strong> a few domestic agrarian and f<strong>in</strong>ancialcapitals, landed oligarchic (and creole 5 ) elites and cash-abundant drug-barons. All <strong>of</strong> them, <strong>in</strong>different but <strong>in</strong>terconnected ways, play a major role <strong>in</strong> current land resources control grabb<strong>in</strong>g.International f<strong>in</strong>ancial capital also plays a key role <strong>in</strong> these <strong>in</strong>dustries beyond speculatively(though <strong>of</strong>ten volatilely) push<strong>in</strong>g up the world prices <strong>of</strong> the different outputs <strong>of</strong> the sugarcaneand the oil palm. Sugarcane agribus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> receive up to 93% <strong>of</strong> their credits <strong>in</strong> USdollars dur<strong>in</strong>g 2011 (http://en.centralamericadata.com accessed on 19 April, 2012). Besides, one<strong>of</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> players <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’s oil palm <strong>in</strong>dustry was until December 2011 a locally<strong>in</strong>corporated subsidiary <strong>of</strong> a USA agrodiesel producer owned by Goldman Sachs and <strong>The</strong>Carlyle Group (see Solano 2010). Furthermore, <strong>in</strong>ternational f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions are alsosupport<strong>in</strong>g the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses’ <strong>in</strong>vestment strategy beyond discursive, regulatory and<strong>in</strong>frastructural support. <strong>The</strong> Inter-American Development Bank (IDB) granted US$150 million to“sugar and bioenergy companies and exporters [especially] <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>, Nicaragua, Dom<strong>in</strong>icanRepublic, El Salvador and north-eastern Brazil” (IDB January 16, 2009). By December 2011, theInternational F<strong>in</strong>ance Corporation <strong>of</strong> the World Bank Group and the IDB had granted up to US$222 million <strong>in</strong> loans to the biggest <strong>Guatemala</strong>n sugarcane agribus<strong>in</strong>ess to allow its go<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>fshore<strong>in</strong> a “Trans-Lat<strong>in</strong>a” fashion (ECLAC 2006, Borras et al. 2012:860): purchas<strong>in</strong>g land, mills anddistilleries <strong>in</strong> Honduras, Nicaragua and El Salvador, and develop<strong>in</strong>g a jo<strong>in</strong>t-venture with majorColombian and Brazilian sugarcane agribus<strong>in</strong>esses to build a distillery-mill complex <strong>in</strong> Brazil.Consider<strong>in</strong>g the former dynamics, we argue that <strong>in</strong>vestment by sugarcane and oil palmagribus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> is be<strong>in</strong>g steered by a common, two-fold strategy. On the one hand,they are temporally deferr<strong>in</strong>g their <strong>in</strong>vestment by allocat<strong>in</strong>g current boom<strong>in</strong>g-revenues to highcost/long-termendeavors (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g land, mills and distilleries). On the other hand, they are(re)adapt<strong>in</strong>g new territories for expand<strong>in</strong>g agro<strong>in</strong>dustrial cultivation <strong>of</strong> sugarcane and oil palm.Thus, similarly to fellow contemporary extractivist capitals <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> (e.g. m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gcorporations, see Holt-Giménez 2008) the <strong>in</strong>vestment strategy <strong>of</strong> the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses issimultaneously steered by both economic and political logics <strong>of</strong> power <strong>in</strong> capitalism.470% <strong>of</strong> total production <strong>of</strong> both sugar and crude palm oil, and 90% <strong>of</strong> total production <strong>of</strong> ethanol, were exported <strong>in</strong>2010.5 <strong>Guatemala</strong> has an estimated 2011 population <strong>of</strong> near 14 million people (INE 2002). It <strong>in</strong>cludes 24 peoples: twentytwoMaya, the X<strong>in</strong>ka, the Garifuna, and the Lad<strong>in</strong>os which <strong>in</strong>clude all the population who does not consider be<strong>in</strong>gneither <strong>in</strong>digenous nor Creole (who dist<strong>in</strong>ctively <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Guatemala</strong>n case claim to be direct European descendants).6
In short, we argue that this new extractivist political economy differs from the overwhelm<strong>in</strong>glypolitical (or extra-economic) one <strong>of</strong> direct and coercive territorial command with the purpose <strong>of</strong>appropriat<strong>in</strong>g labor and natural resources, which underp<strong>in</strong>ned export plantation models dur<strong>in</strong>gcolonial times and (arguably) even until the mid-1980s. It is also different from the orthodoxneoliberal political economy, ma<strong>in</strong>ly articulated through entic<strong>in</strong>g economic forms <strong>of</strong> surplusappropriation through labor and credit markets as well as through globalized commodity valuecha<strong>in</strong>s. <strong>The</strong> new extractivist political economy <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> is a synergic blend <strong>of</strong> the formerand the later; <strong>of</strong> overtly entic<strong>in</strong>g but coercive when necessary government tactics undereconomic and political logics <strong>of</strong> power. It is an expression <strong>of</strong> the orthodox neoliberal politicaleconomy reshaped under current world-historic juncture <strong>of</strong> convergent crises, and thus eager toachieve higher place-based control <strong>of</strong> land resources. It is constitutive <strong>of</strong> a new governmentrationality which, <strong>in</strong> long<strong>in</strong>g for legitimation, has to steer conducts <strong>in</strong> less openly coercive waysthan dur<strong>in</strong>g colonialism and the post-colonial traditional estate system.Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, on the one hand, “the molecular process <strong>of</strong> capital accumulation” (Harvey 2003:26) is articulated through the value cha<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> aforementioned land resources-related global hubs<strong>of</strong> capital accumulation. This economic logic <strong>of</strong> power is enabled by uni-, bi- and multilateraltrade, <strong>in</strong>vestment, energy and <strong>in</strong>tellectual property agreements and policy <strong>in</strong>strumentsmushroom<strong>in</strong>g from the mid-1980s onwards but dist<strong>in</strong>ctively molded by contemporary needs forcapital accumulation and energy security, as well as by climate change mitigation imperatives 6 .Augment<strong>in</strong>g these <strong>in</strong>ternational agreements there is an array <strong>of</strong> domestic normative and policyframeworks, and a bundle <strong>of</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial and fiscal subsidies to support the <strong>in</strong>vestment strategy <strong>of</strong>the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses and fellow extractivist corporations (see Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2008and 2011). Among them, the (de jure) exemption <strong>of</strong> the agribus<strong>in</strong>esses from the value added taxon their export sales and their (de facto) exemption from the land tax are very tell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> thecharacter <strong>of</strong> the government rationality <strong>in</strong> a state with a fiscal contribution to GDP below 10%.Not surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, the labor share <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’s GDP decreased from 33.4% <strong>in</strong> 2001 to 30.6% <strong>in</strong>2009 and the capital share grew from 38.2% to 40.7% dur<strong>in</strong>g the same time span 7 .On the other hand, the <strong>in</strong>vestment and trade system is grow<strong>in</strong>gly subject to critical vigilance byhuman rights, agrarian, environmental and cultural justice movements as well as by specificactors and agencies with<strong>in</strong> the United Nations or the Inter-American Human Rights System 8 .Thus, even though the “global reach <strong>of</strong> capital makes it (<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly?) dependent on localconcentrations <strong>of</strong> extra-economic power” (Wood 2006:32), territorial command is to be exerted<strong>in</strong> (at least) less overtly coercive ways. As Bernste<strong>in</strong> argues, “the economic and social power <strong>of</strong>capital, rooted <strong>in</strong> a system <strong>of</strong> property and commodity relations, has to be secured through itspolitical and ideological rule, exercised -universally but not exclusively - through the state”6 With current Doha Round negotiations literally frozen at the World Trade Organization, the most relevant <strong>of</strong> theseagreements are arguably the “Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic-Central America-USA Free Trade Agreement” (DR-CAFTA),the “EU-Central America Association Agreement”, USA’s “American Clean Energy and Security Act”, EU´s“Renewable Energy Directive”, the “2020 Central American Susta<strong>in</strong>able Energy Strategy”, or the “2008-2017Central American Common Agricultural Policy”. See Alonso-Fradejas et al 2008 and 2011.7 While the poverty head-count ratio reaches 61-62% (INE 2011), <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality by the G<strong>in</strong>i <strong>in</strong>dex peaked53.7% <strong>in</strong> 2006 and undernourishment afflicts 65.9% <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>digenous-rural population (ICEFI-UNICEF 2012).8 See APRODEV, CIDSE, CIFCA, FIAN and Vía Campes<strong>in</strong>a 2011; OHCHR, 2012; Anaya, 2011; De Schutter,2010; and IACHR, 2010.7
(2010a:16). Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, recent territorialization strategies developed by the <strong>Guatemala</strong>n state tocontrol land resources and populations should <strong>in</strong>tervene “<strong>in</strong> the delicate balance <strong>of</strong> social andeconomic processes no more, and no less, than is required to adjust, optimize and susta<strong>in</strong>them” (Foucault 1991, <strong>in</strong> Li 2007:277 stress added). Contemporary government practices <strong>in</strong> therealms <strong>of</strong> labor, social policy (conditional cash transfer programmes) and especially land andnatural resources are very tell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the entic<strong>in</strong>g character <strong>of</strong> current territorialization strategies<strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> (even though coercion and violence are not just a nightmare from the past, as wewill discuss further on).One crucial territorialization strategy has been the enforcement <strong>of</strong> a Market Assisted <strong>Land</strong>Reform (MALR) from the 1996 Peace Accords onwards to “advocate for voluntary transactionsbetween ‘will<strong>in</strong>g sellers’ and ‘will<strong>in</strong>g buyers’ and the removal <strong>of</strong> various ‘distortions’ from landand agricultural markets” (Lahiff et al. 2007:1,417). S<strong>in</strong>ce then, a <strong>Land</strong> Fund (FONTIERRAS)was developed under the tutelage <strong>of</strong> the World Bank that grants subsidized credit, f<strong>in</strong>ancialsupport and technical assistance to groups <strong>of</strong> landless and near landless families and manages the<strong>of</strong>ficial land regularization and titl<strong>in</strong>g programme, together with the National Cadastral Registryfrom 2005 onwards. FONTIERRAS was able to redistribute just 4% <strong>of</strong> the arable land to lessthan 5% <strong>of</strong> the (near)landless families from 1997 to 2008. Many <strong>of</strong> the families which accessedto land through a FONTIERRAS credit have already sold, and most <strong>of</strong> those who have not are<strong>in</strong>capable <strong>of</strong> cop<strong>in</strong>g with their (grow<strong>in</strong>g) debt with FONTIERRAS. <strong>The</strong>re are several reasonsbeh<strong>in</strong>d these regressive outcomes <strong>of</strong> the MALR <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> 9 , among which the farm<strong>in</strong>gdifficulties due to both the <strong>of</strong>ten low quality/over-utilized lands redistributed and the economicdifficulties for peasant farm<strong>in</strong>g under structural adjustment conditions are <strong>of</strong> great relevance.But while FONTIERRAS’ outcomes regard<strong>in</strong>g land redistribution are a great fiasco, those onland titl<strong>in</strong>g have been paradoxically successful. <strong>The</strong> historical claim <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous and peasantpopulations to better ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> and control their access to land through a state-sanctioneddocument was narrowly rendered under the neoliberal government rationality as a claim for<strong>in</strong>dividual freehold land titl<strong>in</strong>g (over other legally-b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g forms <strong>of</strong> ownership 10 ) <strong>in</strong> order togenerate private property rights over tenured land (without consider<strong>in</strong>g other alternative andlegally-b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g land tenancy and use rights). Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, many community lands over whichfarm<strong>in</strong>g rights used to be collectively distributed were split up, privatized and titled under<strong>in</strong>dividual property rights. By <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>digenous and peasant populations <strong>in</strong>to theneoliberal ownership society (Ybarra 2010) conditions were set for “safe property rights [to]allow for markets to transfer land towards more efficient uses and producers” (World Bank2007:138, emphasis added). This has resulted <strong>in</strong> the legal dispossession <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>digenouspeasantry, and not necessarily for the sake <strong>of</strong> ‘productive efficiency’ as we will further argue.9 <strong>The</strong> G<strong>in</strong>i coefficient regard<strong>in</strong>g land distribution rose from 0.83 <strong>in</strong> 1960 to 0.84 <strong>in</strong> 2003 (INE 2004) mean<strong>in</strong>g thatalready by 2003, <strong>in</strong> the onset <strong>of</strong> the recent land rush, 78% <strong>of</strong> the arable land was controlled by 8% <strong>of</strong> thelandholders. About MALR performance <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> see Garoz and Gauster 2002, Garoz, et al. 2005, and Gausterand Isakson 2007.10 Includ<strong>in</strong>g here the counter-revolutionary, state-orchestrated form <strong>of</strong> collective land ownership (CollectiveAgrarian Patrimonies) and the state-recognized cooperative land ownership dist<strong>in</strong>ctively promoted by CatholicOrders embrac<strong>in</strong>g the liberation theology prescriptions8
Together with the MALR and the land titl<strong>in</strong>g programme, two more territorialization strategiesunder neoliberal government rationality must be considered when discuss<strong>in</strong>g contemporary landcontrol grabb<strong>in</strong>g dynamics. First, 31% <strong>of</strong> the national territory is enclosed s<strong>in</strong>ce 1989 under the<strong>Guatemala</strong>n System <strong>of</strong> Protected Areas. <strong>The</strong> agrarian frontier is legally closed with<strong>in</strong> theseprotected areas which are <strong>of</strong>ten managed big (<strong>in</strong>ter)national conservation NGOs, even thoughmany were previously populated. Second, International F<strong>in</strong>ancial Institutions, with a grow<strong>in</strong>gparticipation <strong>of</strong> the Brazilian Development Banks (especially <strong>of</strong> the BNDES), are support<strong>in</strong>galready highly <strong>in</strong>debted Central American states to f<strong>in</strong>ance the <strong>in</strong>frastructure mega-projects<strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the formerly Puebla-Panama Plan, re-launched <strong>in</strong> 2008 as the MesoamericanIntegration and Development Project. This large <strong>in</strong>frastructure corridor which hubs <strong>in</strong> Colombiawith the Initiative for the Integration <strong>of</strong> Regional Infrastructure <strong>in</strong> South America (IIRSA) isbe<strong>in</strong>g developed to better allow for the new extractivist corporate <strong>in</strong>vestments 11 .<strong>Land</strong> control grabb<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms by sugarcane and oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong><strong>Guatemala</strong>’s northern lowlandsSugarcane and specially oil palm plantations are expand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> throughout the northern lowlandsregion encompass<strong>in</strong>g 47% <strong>of</strong> the national territory (see Figure 1). This essay draws on appliedresearch that has been carried out s<strong>in</strong>ce 2006 <strong>in</strong> twenty villages from six different municipalitieswith<strong>in</strong> this region: Chisec, Fray Bartolomé de las Casas and Panzós (<strong>in</strong> Alta Verapaz) El Estor(<strong>in</strong> Izabal), Ixcan (<strong>in</strong> Quiché) and Sayaxché (<strong>in</strong> Petén). Overall, these villages have an estimated2010 population <strong>of</strong> more than half a million people <strong>of</strong> which 77% is rural and 90% <strong>in</strong>digenous,ma<strong>in</strong>ly Maya-Q’eqchi’ (here<strong>in</strong>after Q’eqchi’). Research methods <strong>in</strong>clude policy analysis, ageographic <strong>in</strong>formation system analysis <strong>of</strong> land use changes, a gender-divided householdsurvey 12 , a series <strong>of</strong> focus groups, <strong>in</strong>terviews with a wide range <strong>of</strong> actors and participatoryobservation 13 .11 Specific projects <strong>of</strong> the k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> are gathered under the ‘2005-2015 National Competitiveness Agenda’,which has been recently updated 2012-2021 time span.12 <strong>The</strong> survey was conducted <strong>in</strong> 2010. <strong>The</strong> sample was stratified by municipality (significance level 5%) and<strong>in</strong>cluded 294 randomly selected households from twenty hamlets <strong>in</strong> the six aforementioned municipalities.Interviews were held <strong>in</strong> Q’eqchi’ language with both female- and male-heads-<strong>of</strong>-household (where both available)and always separately to achieve higher confidentiality.13 On research methodology and specific methods see Alonso-Fradejas, Alonzo and Dürr (2008), and Alonso-Fradejas, Caal and Ch<strong>in</strong>chilla (2011).9
Figure 1: Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative map <strong>of</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>*.* <strong>The</strong> outer circle entails the northern lowlands region and the <strong>in</strong>ner one the <strong>in</strong>vestigated areaSource: Government <strong>of</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> 2009. Scale: 1:3,000,000Former military regimes sponsored the agricultural colonization <strong>of</strong> this tropical forest region(below 500 meters above sea level) <strong>in</strong> compliance with the counter-revolutionary land policiesmushroom<strong>in</strong>g throughout Lat<strong>in</strong> America after the 1961 Alliance for Progress Initiative. S<strong>in</strong>cethen, thousands <strong>of</strong> landless and near-landless families from all over the country, but especiallygroups <strong>of</strong> Maya-Q’eqchi’ families (here<strong>in</strong>after Q’eqchi’) from Alta Verapaz fly<strong>in</strong>g away fromthe exploitative ‘colonato regime’ 14 <strong>in</strong> traditional estates and/or from the genocidal violence <strong>of</strong>the <strong>in</strong>ternal armed conflict 15 , arrived <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands <strong>in</strong> search <strong>of</strong> farm land. Traditionallanded upper classes, small and medium lad<strong>in</strong>o (non-<strong>in</strong>digenous) cattle ranchers and militarymen and state <strong>of</strong>ficials rewarded with land by the state 16 arrived also <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlandsdur<strong>in</strong>g the second half <strong>of</strong> the twentieth century, together with this majority <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenouspopulation.<strong>The</strong> Q’eqchi’ is one <strong>of</strong> the largest and arguably more traditional <strong>of</strong> the twenty-two Maya peoples<strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>. Q’eqchi’ families orig<strong>in</strong>ally settled <strong>in</strong> communities <strong>of</strong> middle peasant householdsliv<strong>in</strong>g ma<strong>in</strong>ly on swidden farm<strong>in</strong>g. It is worth not<strong>in</strong>g that there was already important Q’eqchi’migration waves from the highlands <strong>of</strong> Alta Verapaz Department to the northern lowlands dur<strong>in</strong>gthe n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century (see Grandia 2009). However, Q’eqchi’ migration strategies throughout14 This social relation comb<strong>in</strong>es wage-work with <strong>in</strong> k<strong>in</strong>d or labor payments to the landlord (patron) <strong>in</strong> exchange <strong>of</strong>the colono’s right to live and harvest self-provision<strong>in</strong>g crops <strong>in</strong> the landlord’s estate. On the colonato regime <strong>in</strong><strong>Guatemala</strong>, see Martínez Peláez, 1992; Cambranes, 1992; Figueroa Ibarra, 1980; and Hurtado, 2008.15However, dur<strong>in</strong>g the 36 years armed conflict, and especially under the early 1980’s military-led scorched earthpolicy, 160 massacres were also carried out along the northern lowlands region. <strong>The</strong> 1996 Peace Agreements put an<strong>of</strong>ficial end to a conflict which resulted <strong>in</strong> 200,000 people killed or disappeared. Over 80% <strong>of</strong> the victims werecivilian, rural, Maya <strong>in</strong>digenous people (UN-CEH, 1999).16 It is from with<strong>in</strong> these groups that many drug landed-barons will <strong>of</strong>fspr<strong>in</strong>g by wash<strong>in</strong>g money through land<strong>in</strong>vestments.10
an extended territory (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the southern part <strong>of</strong> border<strong>in</strong>g Belize) as a means to access toland avoid<strong>in</strong>g conflicts were handicapped from 1990 onwards. It is <strong>in</strong> this year that the agrarianfrontier was <strong>of</strong>ficially closed by the decree <strong>of</strong> the 21,600 km 2 Mayan Biosphere Reserve <strong>in</strong> thedepartment <strong>of</strong> Petén, together with a series <strong>of</strong> other protected areas throughout the northernlowlands 17 .It is <strong>in</strong> this milieu that land resources are be<strong>in</strong>g control-grabbed from the mid-2000s onwards todevelop sugarcane and especially oil palm plantations. This is happen<strong>in</strong>g through a variety <strong>of</strong>mechanisms, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g 1) long term (25 year) leases from estate owners and ranchers; 2)purchases <strong>of</strong> medium and large traditional estates and ranches; 3) purchases <strong>of</strong> land from smalland medium peasant-farmers; 4) contract-farm<strong>in</strong>g agreements with a few large sugarcane or oilpalm producers; and 5) a three party contract-farm<strong>in</strong>g pilot programme among middle peasants,the oil palm <strong>in</strong>dustry and the government. <strong>The</strong>se land deals result <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>ound changes <strong>in</strong> theland use and <strong>in</strong> the control over land-based wealth, as we will discuss subsequently.<strong>Land</strong> use changes and shift<strong>in</strong>g control over land-based wealth<strong>The</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> flex-crop plantations <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands has caused dramatic direct and<strong>in</strong>direct land use changes as well. In sharp contrast with observed trends elsewhere (De<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ger etal., 2011), control-grabbed land resources <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> are not kept dormant as speculative<strong>in</strong>vestments but <strong>in</strong>stead are rapidly put under <strong>in</strong>tensive production. Figures 2 and 3 summarizethe ma<strong>in</strong> actual and potential direct land use changes associated with expand<strong>in</strong>g oil palmagro<strong>in</strong>dustrial plantations <strong>in</strong> the Northern Lowlands.Figure 2: <strong>Land</strong> uses <strong>in</strong> the year 2005 <strong>in</strong> the oil palm cultivated lands <strong>in</strong> 2010 <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>´snorthern lowlandsFood-crops 23%23%Grazelands 10%38%Traditional exportplantations 2%10%Ra<strong>in</strong>forest 27%Wetlands 1%1%27%2%Grasslands 38%Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011: 62.17 All <strong>of</strong> them part <strong>of</strong> the 1989-established <strong>Guatemala</strong>n System <strong>of</strong> Protected Areas.11
Figure 3: <strong>Land</strong> uses <strong>in</strong> the year 2005 <strong>in</strong> the additional suitable lands* for oil palm cultivation <strong>in</strong><strong>Guatemala</strong>´s northern lowlands18%Food crops 18%39%4%2%Grazelands 4%Traditional exportplantations 2%Ra<strong>in</strong>forest 36%Wetlands 1%1%36%Grasslands 39%*Accord<strong>in</strong>g to calculations <strong>of</strong> suitable land for oil palm cultivation <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> by the Geographic InformationLaboratory <strong>of</strong> the M<strong>in</strong>istry <strong>of</strong> Food, Livestock and Agriculture, year 2008.Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011: 64.<strong>The</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> sugarcane and oil palm is also trigger<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>direct land use changes. Many <strong>of</strong>the ranchers who leased or sold their land to the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> the northernlowlands are grabb<strong>in</strong>g control over peasant farms, other estates and ranches, and forested landsbeyond the legal agrarian frontier. <strong>The</strong>se ranchers <strong>of</strong>ten hire Q’eqchi’ and other workers to cutdown forest and grab land <strong>in</strong>side the Mayan Biosphere Reserve <strong>in</strong> the department <strong>of</strong> Petén.Together with the cattle ranchers many dispossessed peasants are also encroach<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this andother protected areas along the Northern Lowlands <strong>in</strong> search <strong>of</strong> farm land for subsistence.Build<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> these two effects <strong>of</strong> the corporate land control grabs, a racialized discourse is erectedfrom the dom<strong>in</strong>ant government rationality to “censure Q’eqchi people as bad environmentalists”(Ybarra 2010:17). Meanwhile, sugarcane and oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> receivemillionaire payments for environmental services through Kyoto Protocol’s Clean DevelopmentMechanism and are part <strong>of</strong> different socio-environmental <strong>in</strong>ternational certification schemes suchas the roundtables on Susta<strong>in</strong>able Palm Oil and on Bi<strong>of</strong>uels, the Ra<strong>in</strong>forest Alliance Certificate,and the Better Sugarcane Initiative (see Alonso-Fradejas et al., 2008, 2011).<strong>The</strong>se land use changes are shift<strong>in</strong>g control over land-based wealth from the local (cultivat<strong>in</strong>g)territory and classes towards distant, non-cultivat<strong>in</strong>g classes (national oligarchy and <strong>in</strong>ternationalhubs <strong>of</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancialised capital). Moreover, s<strong>in</strong>ce peasant crops/systems generate up to ten timesmore ‘local wealth’ per hectare than corporate sugarcane and oil palm (see Figure 4 below) theterritorial economy results badly benefitted as a whole from expand<strong>in</strong>g flex-crop plantations.12
Figure 4: Gross Territorial Product* per hectare <strong>of</strong> peasant crops/systems, sugarcane and oil palm<strong>in</strong> the Polochic Valley, year 2008, <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>n Quetzals (1US$≈8GTQ).* <strong>The</strong> Gross Territorial Product for each crop is obta<strong>in</strong>ed by subtract<strong>in</strong>g the crop-related Net Outside Payments(remunerat<strong>in</strong>g agents <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>ks <strong>of</strong> the value cha<strong>in</strong> outside the territory) to its Gross Added Value. <strong>The</strong> Gross AddedValue is obta<strong>in</strong>ed by subtract<strong>in</strong>g Total Purchases <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts from Total Sales for each crop. Information gathered <strong>in</strong>the municipalities <strong>of</strong> Panzós and El Estor.Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2008:70.<strong>Land</strong> control grabb<strong>in</strong>g and changes <strong>in</strong> property relationsRight <strong>of</strong> ownership changes, <strong>in</strong> strict sense, have only been prompted by two out <strong>of</strong> the fiveaforementioned mechanisms for land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g by the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>ess, i.e., those<strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g actual land purchases from landed upper classes and different classes <strong>of</strong> peasantries toestablish vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated plantations (numbers 2 and 3 above). <strong>The</strong>se are the most frequentexpansion mechanisms and form <strong>of</strong> production <strong>of</strong> the sugarcane and oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses.<strong>Land</strong> purchases have prompted two dist<strong>in</strong>ctive dynamics on land property, namely landreconcentration, when medium and large estates are put together under production as part <strong>of</strong> alarger plantation, and land concentration when farms previously owned by peasant farmers areput together <strong>in</strong>to a larger plantation.<strong>Land</strong> control grabb<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands has resulted <strong>in</strong> the expulsion and displacement <strong>of</strong>hundreds <strong>of</strong> families and even <strong>of</strong> entire communities. An estimated 11% <strong>of</strong> the total peasanthouseholds from the <strong>in</strong>vestigated areas, ma<strong>in</strong>ly Q’eqchi’, lost their land tenancy rights dur<strong>in</strong>g thelast decade. Of these cases, land tenancy rights <strong>of</strong> the Q’eqchi’ peasantry were taken directly byagribus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> 92.5% <strong>of</strong> the cases, and by cattle ranchers <strong>in</strong> the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g cases. Dozens <strong>of</strong>hamlets have been reduced to a small hous<strong>in</strong>g area and at least ten cases are known where thehamlet as a whole, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g houses, school and churches, were gobbled up completely by a flexcropplantation. Although no empirical data is available before the year 2010, accord<strong>in</strong>g to13
different <strong>in</strong>formants the direct and <strong>in</strong>direct, voluntary or coercive <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>of</strong> peasants <strong>in</strong>land deals with the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>ess has dist<strong>in</strong>ctively contributed to current atomization <strong>of</strong>the land tenancy among the northern lowlands’ peasantry. Figure 5 below shows the alreadyunequal land tenancy panorama <strong>in</strong> 2010 among the surveyed households, with almost a third <strong>of</strong>the total families (near)landless.Figure 5: Rural households by land tenancy <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’s northern lowlands, year 2010Between more than 48 and 64 ha1,4%Between more than 21 and 48 ha17,5%Between more than 7 and 21 ha18,5%Between 1 and 7 ha32,5%Less than 1 ha15%<strong>Land</strong>less15,1%0% 5% 10% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35%Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011:66Agribus<strong>in</strong>esses are basically <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> landed-property without labor liabilities with a proper<strong>in</strong>scription <strong>in</strong> the General Property Registry 18 . Thus, grabbed-land from the Q’eqchi’ peasantrywas titled under <strong>in</strong>dividual freehold <strong>in</strong> 72% <strong>of</strong> the cases and under two other forms <strong>of</strong> thirdparties-imposed collective land property rights (Cooperatives or Collective AgrarianPatrimonies) <strong>in</strong> the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g (Alonso-Fradejas et al., 2012). <strong>The</strong> fact that grabbed-land from theQ’eqchi’ peasantry were <strong>of</strong>ficially titled by FONTIERRAS leads to the state see<strong>in</strong>g these landdeals as the MALR-k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> envisaged voluntary transactions between ‘will<strong>in</strong>g’ sellers andbuyers. Neoliberal land titl<strong>in</strong>g resulted <strong>in</strong> a fundamental territorialization strategy also undercontemporary dom<strong>in</strong>ant government rationality to facilitate a subtle, legal dispossession <strong>of</strong> theQ’eqchi’ peasantry.In a survey for this research, half <strong>of</strong> the male heads-<strong>of</strong>-household currently work<strong>in</strong>g for a flexcropagribus<strong>in</strong>ess said they sold their land because it was ‘unproductive’ and the other halfbecause they were ‘highly <strong>in</strong>debted.’ Of those male heads-<strong>of</strong>-household who did not work for aflex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>ess, half <strong>of</strong> them said they were ‘forced’ to sell their land, another third saidthey sold it because it was ‘unproductive’ and the rest because they were ‘highly <strong>in</strong>debted.’ Insharp contrast, 86% <strong>of</strong> surveyed female heads-<strong>of</strong>-household openly opposed these land deals. Letus dig deeper to achieve a better understand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> these reasons to participate <strong>in</strong> land deals.18 It has been common then for (<strong>of</strong>ten more overtly violent) cattle ranchers to purchase the land <strong>in</strong> advance <strong>in</strong> orderto deal with these legal issues, and resell it afterwards to a flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>ess at a higher price14
As po<strong>in</strong>ted out by Q’eqchi’ men engaged <strong>in</strong> land deals, high <strong>in</strong>debtedness 19 has played a majorrole <strong>in</strong> ‘voluntary’ peasant dispossession. <strong>The</strong> private, <strong>in</strong>dividual land property rights endorsedby FONTIERRAS might have augmented peasants’ abilities to access to formal credit, butannual <strong>in</strong>terest rates by the private bank<strong>in</strong>g sector (pr<strong>of</strong>it and non-pr<strong>of</strong>it-led) float<strong>in</strong>g between18%-26% (usurers’ can reach 120%) 20 have either prevented peasants from apply<strong>in</strong>g for a creditor led them to lose the land used as collateral when <strong>in</strong>capable <strong>of</strong> cop<strong>in</strong>g with debt loads.Indebtedness is l<strong>in</strong>ked to the issue <strong>of</strong> ‘unproductive’ lands and/or decreas<strong>in</strong>g agriculturalproductivity as well. This is a contentious issue which is better understood when problematizedbeyond dom<strong>in</strong>ant approaches render<strong>in</strong>g complex sets <strong>of</strong> socio-agroecological relations to narrow,green revolution-based technical discourses around ‘yield-gaps’ (World Bank 2007, De<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ger etal. 2011). It is <strong>in</strong> fact very important to consider at least three ma<strong>in</strong>, <strong>in</strong>terrelated determ<strong>in</strong>antsover peasant farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>herited from the economic liberalization dynamics under the orthodoxneoliberal government rationality from the mid-1980s to the mid-2000s <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>.First, the value dispossession (see Deere and de Janvry 1979 and Araghi 2009) to which smallscalefarmers were subject through the enforcement <strong>of</strong> below-cost-<strong>of</strong>-production (dump<strong>in</strong>g)prices from imported and subsidized food-staples (corn, rice, wheat) as local prices <strong>of</strong>reference 21 . Second, the <strong>Guatemala</strong>n economy Structural Adjustment Programme enforced from1996 onwards resulted <strong>in</strong> the privatizations <strong>of</strong> the state agrarian development bank, <strong>in</strong> them<strong>in</strong>imization <strong>of</strong> the public <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> appropriate agricultural technologies and <strong>in</strong> thedisappearance <strong>of</strong> agricultural extension agencies and the food-commodities board. And third, it ismost important to analyze the productivity problematic consider<strong>in</strong>g the ways <strong>in</strong> which <strong>in</strong>dividualland ownership has drastically reshaped the Q’eqchi’-system <strong>of</strong> swidden farm<strong>in</strong>g and associatedsocial relations.On the one hand, <strong>in</strong>dividualized land ownership has contributed to the shift from Q’eqchi’ <strong>of</strong>tencommunally agreed distribution <strong>of</strong> farm<strong>in</strong>g plots to every family <strong>in</strong> the community on the basis<strong>of</strong> their reproductive needs, while keep<strong>in</strong>g forest areas <strong>of</strong> communal access (Grünberg 2003,Grandia 2009) towards differentiated, univocally ‘fixed’ (across time and space) family-ownedplots, usually enclos<strong>in</strong>g all community land resources. This restructur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> property relationshas forced nearly eight out <strong>of</strong> ten Q’eqchi’ peasant households <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands tonecessarily move from what used to be a relatively social and agro-ecologically efficientswidden farm<strong>in</strong>g system towards a more <strong>in</strong>tensive farm<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>in</strong> tune with the conditionssettled by the new property regime. Evidence from the region’s karstic soils with little organicmatter, where apply<strong>in</strong>g grow<strong>in</strong>g amounts <strong>of</strong> chemical fertilizers is as expensive as it is relatively<strong>in</strong>effective, shows that the key towards enhanced productivity lies more <strong>in</strong> the ability <strong>of</strong> the19 Result<strong>in</strong>g from a chronic <strong>in</strong>ability <strong>of</strong> the peasant household to face the payments associated with credits f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>gfrom farm<strong>in</strong>g activities to unexpected medical expenses.20 <strong>The</strong> 2010 annual <strong>in</strong>flation rate <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> was <strong>of</strong> 5.39% (BANGUAT, 2012).21 <strong>The</strong>oretically, grow<strong>in</strong>g demand <strong>of</strong> these food-staples by the global feed-food-fuel complexes should allow forlocal price <strong>in</strong>creases. So far, however, local prices <strong>of</strong> food are <strong>in</strong> fact <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g but oligopoly control over valuecha<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> some regions, and <strong>in</strong>creased costs <strong>of</strong> production and transportation reflect<strong>in</strong>g higher oil <strong>in</strong>ternationalprices, are mak<strong>in</strong>g it hard for food-staple producers <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> to benefit from higher prices for their product. Netfood-buyer rural and urban households, however, are badly impacted.15
household to dedicate higher amounts <strong>of</strong> labor (<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g ‘self-exploitation’ 22 ) to <strong>in</strong>tensify thefarm<strong>in</strong>g system <strong>in</strong> a way which is less dependent on synthetic <strong>in</strong>puts, than <strong>in</strong> a new “GreenRevolution miracle” (M<strong>in</strong>gorría and Gamboa 2010:51, Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011:143). Thisand the lack<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> appropriate extension services are reflected on the op<strong>in</strong>ions <strong>of</strong> different types<strong>of</strong> small-scale farmers about how to enhance land productivity summarized <strong>in</strong> Figure 6 below.Figure 6: Small-scale farmers’ op<strong>in</strong>ions about enhanc<strong>in</strong>g land productivity <strong>in</strong> the northernlowlands, year 2010.2% No idea ('some' advice needed) 35%22%35%Technical advice 22%Leave the land fallow 12%4%Reforestation 4%12%25%Organic fertilisation 25%Others 2%Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011:141On the other hand, <strong>in</strong>dividual land ownership has not only commoditized most <strong>of</strong> the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gcommunity land resources but has also opened the door for a grow<strong>in</strong>g monetization <strong>of</strong> traditionalreciprocity mechanisms among the Q’eqchi’ peasantry (Scott 1976. See also Grandia 2009). As aresult, for example, non-family labor is now <strong>of</strong>ten paid <strong>in</strong> cash when previously exchanged.F<strong>in</strong>ally, the aforementioned mechanisms <strong>of</strong> ‘voluntary’ dispossession are <strong>of</strong>ten augmented byviolence. Peasants who have refused to sell at non-negotiable prices have been violently harassedand physical evictions are commonplace. We will dig further <strong>in</strong> the contrast<strong>in</strong>g entic<strong>in</strong>g andcoercive tactics <strong>of</strong> govern<strong>in</strong>g land resources and populations after discuss<strong>in</strong>g about employmentdynamics and the labor regime shift <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands.Employment and the flexible labor regime <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’s northern lowlandsSelf-employment as a small-scale farmer was the most important employment source <strong>in</strong> thenorthern lowlands <strong>in</strong> 2010. Furthermore, as Table 1 shows below for the active economicpopulation employed out <strong>of</strong> the household, small-scale farm<strong>in</strong>g was also the ma<strong>in</strong> source <strong>of</strong>22 Beyond its more direct sense <strong>of</strong> “excruciat<strong>in</strong>g labor by underfed peasant families” (Len<strong>in</strong> and Kautsky <strong>in</strong> Shan<strong>in</strong>1966:6) Chayanov argued how variable degrees <strong>of</strong> ‘self-exploitation’ by the peasant labor act as a mechanismunique to the peasant family to leverage the labor force with<strong>in</strong> the household towards the goal <strong>of</strong> provision<strong>in</strong>g thefamily consumption needs (even at a m<strong>in</strong>imum).16
wage-labor, followed by oil palm plantations, and with very little <strong>in</strong>cidence <strong>of</strong> non-agriculturaljob sources.Table 1: Employment sources for rural households <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands, year 2010Small-scalefarm<strong>in</strong>gOil palmplantationOtherplantationsEstate/haciendaNon-agriculturalcompanyPrivatesecurityPublic sector(civil servant)Army NGO Others Total40% 35% 3% 4% 1% 3% 6% 3% 1% 4% 100%Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al 2011:151.<strong>The</strong> non-mechanized flex-crop plantations (and extensive cattle-ranch<strong>in</strong>g) <strong>in</strong> the northernlowlands are much less labor-<strong>in</strong>tensive than small-scale farm<strong>in</strong>g crops/systems, as Figure 7shows below. Moreover, every direct agricultural job <strong>in</strong> an oil palm/sugarcane plantationrespectively contributes with 0.7/0.4 <strong>in</strong>direct jobs upstream the value cha<strong>in</strong> (<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrial and/ortrad<strong>in</strong>g sectors), while every direct job <strong>in</strong> small-scale-farmed corn, rice and p<strong>in</strong>eapple (forexample) respectively contributes with 1.1, 1.6 and 1.9 <strong>in</strong>direct employments (Dürr 2011).Figure 7: Work<strong>in</strong>g Days (W.D.) per hectare and year <strong>in</strong> small-scale farm<strong>in</strong>g crops/systems,sugarcane, oil palm and cattle ranch<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’s northern lowlands, year 2009.200180160140120100806040200Corn/corn Beans Corn/rice Chili P<strong>in</strong>eapple WatermeloncitricscaneLemon/ Roots Pepper Sugar Oil palm CattleW.D. per ha and year 112 56 78 184 68 121 114 88 130 36 52 4Source: Dürr 2011, <strong>in</strong> Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011:153.Moreover, among the (near)landless laborers, hold<strong>in</strong>g less than 1 hectare <strong>of</strong> land, (see Figure 5above) 53% worked <strong>in</strong> 2010 dur<strong>in</strong>g three or more months <strong>in</strong> (Q’eqchi’) small-scale farms, 33%worked for an oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>ess, 7% worked <strong>in</strong> ranches or traditional estates and (only) 7%worked <strong>in</strong> non-agricultural activities (Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011). It is strik<strong>in</strong>g that evenwithout social security benefits and earn<strong>in</strong>g around 35% less on average, most landless andoccasional peasant laborers would rather work for other small-scale farmers than for an oil palmagribus<strong>in</strong>ess. Why is this so? Together with the non-unimportant statements regard<strong>in</strong>g that lunch17
is frequently provided and that plantation’s foremen are not harass<strong>in</strong>g them, two fundamentalreasons were put forward by landless laborers from the northern lowlands (Alonso-Fradejas etal., 2011).First, labor processes and associated work<strong>in</strong>g conditions <strong>in</strong> the sugarcane and oil palmplantations are flexibly organized, and hyper-commodified, with compliance <strong>of</strong> the state weaklabor <strong>in</strong>stitutional and policy frameworks. Even though they differ accord<strong>in</strong>g to variousaspects 23 , several employment patterns are found <strong>in</strong> the fact that most <strong>of</strong> the available jobs arecasual, for short time, and very demand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> physical effort and temporal andgeographical flexibility (see also Hurtado and Sánchez 2011). For example, eight out <strong>of</strong> everyten workers <strong>in</strong> oil palm plantations were recruited by third parties <strong>in</strong> 2010, mean<strong>in</strong>g weaker laborliabilities for agribus<strong>in</strong>esses (only 28% <strong>of</strong> the total employees were under a social securityscheme). <strong>The</strong> flexible labor regime’s performance requirements and the idea that “youngsterswork harder and create less trouble” 24 result <strong>in</strong> most flex-crop plantation workers be<strong>in</strong>g relativelyyoung, Q’eqchi’ men. Performance-l<strong>in</strong>ked, piecework wages are also more appeal<strong>in</strong>g to landless,young, Q’eqchi’ men who are encouraged by the agribus<strong>in</strong>esses to “multiply <strong>in</strong> several times the<strong>of</strong>ficial m<strong>in</strong>imum wage, depend<strong>in</strong>g on their capacities and hours worked” 25 .Most dist<strong>in</strong>ctively, the flexible labor regime is prompt<strong>in</strong>g and/or deepen<strong>in</strong>g two dynamicsregard<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>ternal division <strong>of</strong> labor <strong>in</strong> rural Q’eqchi’ households. On the one hand, manyplantation workers are assisted by their children to avoid hir<strong>in</strong>g additional labor to be able tomeet their daily-tasks (see also M<strong>in</strong>gorría and Gamboa 2010). On the other hand, almostcompletely excluded as casual workers by the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses, female 26 heads-<strong>of</strong>householdare <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly struggl<strong>in</strong>g to work their family farms, <strong>in</strong> addition to their householdresponsibilities and grow<strong>in</strong>g participation <strong>in</strong> community government issues. In fact, Q’eqchi’women from the northern lowlands spend 10% to 15% less time on their physiological needs(sleep<strong>in</strong>g, eat<strong>in</strong>g, bath<strong>in</strong>g and so forth) than their male-partners (Gamboa and M<strong>in</strong>gorría 2010) <strong>in</strong>order to cope with the grow<strong>in</strong>g activities <strong>of</strong> their triple workday.Second, the work<strong>in</strong>g day <strong>in</strong> small-scale farm<strong>in</strong>g is shorter, sometimes demand<strong>in</strong>g just half <strong>of</strong> thedaily work<strong>in</strong>g hours required by a flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>ess, as Table 2 shows below.23 Such as the specific agribus<strong>in</strong>ess, the task to perform, the mode <strong>of</strong> recruitment, the worker’s qualification, hisengagement <strong>in</strong> social organizations, and so forth24 Interviewed foremen from various oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses, quoted <strong>in</strong> Alonso-Fradejas et al., 2011:155.25 <strong>Guatemala</strong>’s Oil Palm Growers Guild, www.grepalma.org accessed on 19 April, 2012, translations m<strong>in</strong>e.26 Women are just temporally employed at the greenhouses where the baby oil palms are cropped “because this is adelicate job which is better performed by women” (Interview with the manager <strong>of</strong> a baby oil palms greenhouse,northern lowlands, 5 June 2009).18
Table 2: Workers <strong>in</strong> oil palm plantations and <strong>in</strong> small scale farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands bydaily work<strong>in</strong>g hours, year 2010Oil palm plantationSmall-scale farm<strong>in</strong>gLess than 8 hours/day 11% 51%8 hours/day 61% 36%More than 8 hours/day 28% 13%Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011:157.This allows for workers <strong>in</strong> small-scale farm<strong>in</strong>g to earn a wage and still have time to till theirfarms (<strong>in</strong> owned, leased or borrowed land) and to deal with community work and governmentresponsibilities. Not surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, under similar social and agro-ecological conditions, averagemaize yields were 8% higher and food expenditure 21% lower <strong>in</strong> households where the maleheaddid not work for an oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>ess dur<strong>in</strong>g 2010 (Alonso-Fradejas et al, 2011: 122).This is <strong>of</strong> outstand<strong>in</strong>g importance s<strong>in</strong>ce, as Table 3 shows below, for rural households <strong>in</strong> thenorthern lowlands farm<strong>in</strong>g is the ma<strong>in</strong> source <strong>of</strong> Gross Annual Income (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g both monetary<strong>in</strong>come and self-consumption). And, work<strong>in</strong>g for a flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>of</strong>ten erodes theabilities <strong>of</strong> small-scale farmers to dedicate the work<strong>in</strong>g time their farms require for <strong>in</strong>creasedproductivity, as previously discussed.Table 3: Gross Annual Income sources <strong>of</strong> rural households <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands, year 2010MarketFarm<strong>in</strong>gSelf-consumptionTotal farm<strong>in</strong>gWage-workPublictransfers*Other non-farm<strong>in</strong>come sources**29% 21% 50% 29% 9% 12%*Includ<strong>in</strong>g conditional cash transfers and less importantly the two sacks <strong>of</strong> government-subsidized chemicalfertilizer.**Includ<strong>in</strong>g a variety <strong>of</strong> trade-related activities and, almost residually, remittances from emigrants.Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011:114.As we keep argu<strong>in</strong>g, even landless laborers <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands farm a piece <strong>of</strong> land. AsTable 4 shows below, the amount <strong>of</strong> harvested land <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> parallel to the total amount <strong>of</strong>land held (under ownership or tenancy rights) and it is always higher <strong>in</strong> those households whosemale-head does not work for an oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>ess.19
Table 4: Harvested land by total land and by occupation <strong>of</strong> the male head-<strong>of</strong>-household <strong>in</strong> thenorthern lowlands, year 2010.Harvested land (Ha.)Households by total land (Ha.)Male head-<strong>of</strong>-household work<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> an oil palm plantationMale head-<strong>of</strong>-household NOTwork<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> an oil palm plantationAll householdsLess than 1 Ha 2,3 2,2 2,2More than 1 and less than 21 Ha 4,0 4,4 4,3More than 21 and less than 48 Ha 3,7 5,3 5,3More than 48 and less than 64 Ha 6,5 6,5Total average 3,4 4,2 4,1Source: Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2011:113.Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g, small-scale farm<strong>in</strong>g is paradoxically functional to the agribus<strong>in</strong>esses’ flexiblelabor regime. Monetary <strong>in</strong>come and self-consumption from small-scale farm<strong>in</strong>g, together withthe governmental conditional cash transfers programme <strong>in</strong>augurated <strong>in</strong> 2008 27 , supplementlaborers’ <strong>in</strong>come and thus helps <strong>in</strong> keep<strong>in</strong>g relatively low piece-work wages <strong>in</strong> the flex-cropplantations. 89% <strong>of</strong> the male heads-<strong>of</strong>-household work<strong>in</strong>g for an oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> 2010was also dedicated to farm<strong>in</strong>g, and 78% <strong>of</strong> them were beneficiaries <strong>of</strong> conditional cash transfers.But the higher the amount <strong>of</strong> arable land harvested under flex-crop plantations, the lesser theabilities <strong>of</strong> rural dwellers to access to farm land. This confronts the agribus<strong>in</strong>esses’ <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>grush for land with their convenient co-existence with small-scale food farmers. Evidence fromthe flex-crop plantations-swamped municipalities <strong>of</strong> Panzos and Sayaxché show how, on the oneside, local food prices have become subject <strong>of</strong> regular <strong>in</strong>creases lead<strong>in</strong>g to plantation workers tomobilize, as net food-buyers, for higher piece-work wages. On the other side, <strong>in</strong> a grow<strong>in</strong>glyland-scarce milieu where non- and <strong>of</strong>f-farm jobs are m<strong>in</strong>imal (see Table 2 above) the substitution<strong>of</strong> the more labor-<strong>in</strong>tensive small-scale farms by labor-expell<strong>in</strong>g flex-crop plantations (seeFigure 7 above) allows for agribus<strong>in</strong>esses keep<strong>in</strong>g piece-work wages low. This sets even higherpressure on the contemporary “agrarian question <strong>of</strong> labor” <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>, expressed by Bernste<strong>in</strong>as: “What if the forms <strong>of</strong> capitalism <strong>in</strong> the South today are <strong>in</strong>capable <strong>of</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g sufficient, andsufficiently secure, employment to provide ‘a liv<strong>in</strong>g wage’ to the great majority?” (2006:13).F<strong>in</strong>ally, and deepen<strong>in</strong>g the debate on the modes <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>corporation (DuToit 2004) to the globalfood-feed-fuel value cha<strong>in</strong>s, it is important to give some <strong>in</strong>sights about the three party contractfarm<strong>in</strong>gpilot programme among middle peasants, the oil palm <strong>in</strong>dustry and the government.This pilot programme was <strong>in</strong>augurated <strong>in</strong> 2009 and funded with US$ 1.5 million by thegovernment. It is aimed at convert<strong>in</strong>g 4,200 hectares <strong>of</strong> ‘idle’ peasant land <strong>in</strong>to lucrative oil palmfarms dur<strong>in</strong>g twenty-five years. Peasants receive a US$ 528 per-hectare credit from thegovernment, which is transferred directly to the agribus<strong>in</strong>ess as a payment for seedl<strong>in</strong>gs andagronomic and transport services (Alonso-Fradejas et al., 2011). As stated by the programmeDirector (an eng<strong>in</strong>eer formerly employed by the one and only contract<strong>in</strong>g oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>ess)27 It consists <strong>of</strong> a US$ 37 month-equivalent transfer to female heads-<strong>of</strong>-household who comply with the household’syoung children educational- and health-related requirements <strong>of</strong> the programme.20
“we want to avoid any more land deals lead<strong>in</strong>g to peasant dispossession” 28 . In pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, thecontract-farm<strong>in</strong>g programme does not entail any change <strong>in</strong> property relations. However, besidesthe questionable public subsidy to the agribus<strong>in</strong>ess and the fact that the peasant’s land title isused as collateral <strong>of</strong> the governmental credit, the contracts do not <strong>in</strong>clude crop <strong>in</strong>surance, leav<strong>in</strong>gpeasants to absorb the risks <strong>of</strong> production, nor do they specify who is to pay the highdis<strong>in</strong>vestment costs to rehabilitate soil fertility after twenty-five years when oil palms can nolonger be harvested.Political dynamics <strong>of</strong> change <strong>in</strong> land resources-based social relationsWith<strong>in</strong> the dom<strong>in</strong>ant extractivist political economy, particular social differentiation processes areprompted and/or deepened under economic, political, cultural and symbolical rationales <strong>of</strong>power. On the materialist side, chang<strong>in</strong>g social and property relations <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlandshave resulted <strong>in</strong> both, more heterogeneous class formations and more complex <strong>in</strong>ter- and <strong>in</strong>traclassrelations. <strong>The</strong> oligarchic-yet-transnationalized, flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses have becomedom<strong>in</strong>ant over traditional landed upper classes and territorial political elites. Though mightylarge estate owners and ranchers still rema<strong>in</strong>, many <strong>of</strong> them have developed contract-farm<strong>in</strong>gagreements with the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses and others have sold or leased their land to them.<strong>The</strong>se deals on good terms, however, should not lead us to conclude that chang<strong>in</strong>g dom<strong>in</strong>ancewith<strong>in</strong> the <strong>of</strong>ten compet<strong>in</strong>g-for-resources classes <strong>of</strong> capital is absolutely free <strong>of</strong> conflicts andcontradictions. While clash<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terests among the classes <strong>of</strong> capital are seldom overt <strong>in</strong> nationalpolitics, they can create a lot <strong>of</strong> tension <strong>in</strong> specific, localized sett<strong>in</strong>gs. For <strong>in</strong>stance, it was notunusual to hear ranchers compla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g about the negative impacts <strong>of</strong> expand<strong>in</strong>g flex-cropplantations over watersheds’ availability, contam<strong>in</strong>ated water sources to water their cattlebecause <strong>of</strong> the heavy use <strong>of</strong> agro-chemicals <strong>in</strong> the plantations and especially, about theagribus<strong>in</strong>esses owners’ annoy<strong>in</strong>g distant rule, normally exercised through bus<strong>in</strong>ess ‘fieldmanagers’. This stands for a clash between old-times tactics <strong>of</strong> govern<strong>in</strong>g land resources andpopulations and the ones particular to current extractivist government rationality.Furthermore, chang<strong>in</strong>g property relations and labor regime are splitt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to diverse rural classes<strong>of</strong> labor 29 the rather homogeneous middle peasantry orig<strong>in</strong>ated dur<strong>in</strong>g the agrarian colonization.Most legally-dispossessed Q’eqchi’ peasant families received a payment for their land whichgenerally neither allowed them to boost a non-farm livelihood, nor to rega<strong>in</strong> land ownershipelsewhere as land prices keep ris<strong>in</strong>g. Often, those who rema<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> their communities swelled theranks <strong>of</strong> the landless to work as piecework-wage laborers, occasionally farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> leased orborrowed land. Families under colonato regime who were expelled from control-grabbedtraditional estates and ranches face a similar condition as that <strong>of</strong> the dispossessed families, asalso do the landless youth which became surplus workforce <strong>in</strong> their parents’ squeezed familylabor farms. Indeed, <strong>in</strong>dividual freehold land ownership brought about a system <strong>of</strong> partible<strong>in</strong>heritance among Q’eqchi’ families. This has accelerated land tenancy atomization among the28 Interview <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> City, 21 September 2009.29 Compris<strong>in</strong>g all those who “have to pursue their reproduction through <strong>in</strong>secure, oppressive and <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly‘<strong>in</strong>formalised’ wage employment and/or a range <strong>of</strong> likewise precarious small-scale and <strong>in</strong>secure ‘<strong>in</strong>formal sector’(‘survival’) activity, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g farm<strong>in</strong>g; <strong>in</strong> effect, various and complex comb<strong>in</strong>ations <strong>of</strong> employment and selfemployment”(Bernste<strong>in</strong> 2010b:73).21
peasantry (see Figure 5 above) through the biological development <strong>of</strong> the family (Chayanov1966: 68) <strong>in</strong> a grow<strong>in</strong>gly land-scarce milieu where the population density almost tripled dur<strong>in</strong>gthe last thirty years (INE 2011). In fact, the more autarchic Q’eqchi’ family labor farms <strong>of</strong>twenty years ago stood just for 26% <strong>of</strong> total rural households <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands <strong>in</strong> 2010(Alonso-Fradejas et al, 2011: 66). <strong>The</strong> rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g majority <strong>of</strong> landed peasant households wereeconomically differentiated by their different comb<strong>in</strong>ations <strong>of</strong> own, hired-<strong>in</strong> and/or hired-outlabor, as well as by the range and type <strong>of</strong> crops farmed. Only 23% <strong>of</strong> the landed peasantryfarmed at least one cash-crop (cardamom, rice, cocoa, fruits and/or species) and just 1.03% waspart <strong>of</strong> the government-sponsored, contract-farm<strong>in</strong>g scheme with the oil palm <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> 2010(Alonso-Fradejas et al, 2011: 128).Interdependences and relations among different classes <strong>of</strong> capital and labor <strong>in</strong> the countrysidehave also been dist<strong>in</strong>ctively shaped by chang<strong>in</strong>g social and property relations. Previously semicommodified,patron-client type <strong>of</strong> exploitative-yet-paternalistic relations <strong>of</strong> production <strong>in</strong>traditional estates, owned by <strong>in</strong> situ liv<strong>in</strong>g patrons, fall beh<strong>in</strong>d the hyper-commodified laborregime <strong>of</strong> the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses, controlled by distant oligarchs and shareholders.Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, traditional reciprocity mechanisms are also gradually liable to new clearly-butnarrowlyobjectivized, one-fits-all k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> arrangements between the classes <strong>of</strong> labor and theclasses <strong>of</strong> capital. In this way, materialist social differentiation dynamics are embedded with<strong>in</strong>the cultural, symbolical and political doma<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> social life. Under contemporary extractivistgovernment rationality, cultural, political and symbolical command is essential to supportconditions for accumulation and economic rul<strong>in</strong>g over place-based resources and populations.We have argued how this command over population and peoples is to be most convenientlyexerted nowadays through population’s own will. Thus, entic<strong>in</strong>g tactics <strong>of</strong> government are, <strong>in</strong>pr<strong>in</strong>ciple, to be privileged over coercive ones. In this sense, we have discussed how ‘conductsteer<strong>in</strong>g’ territorialization strategies have been unfold<strong>in</strong>g by the state through labor, social andespecially land and natural resources policies and discourses simplify<strong>in</strong>g (Scott 1998) andrender<strong>in</strong>g technical (Li 2005) complex land-based social relations as a way <strong>of</strong> “detach<strong>in</strong>gproperty from [the control <strong>of</strong>] any public or communal power, <strong>in</strong> order to make it entirely subjectto the purely economic force <strong>of</strong> capital” (Wood 2006: 31). But together with this materialistoutcome, and <strong>in</strong> fact as both a means and an result <strong>of</strong> this economic distribution problematic, thenew extractivist government rationality fuels a cultural distribution conflict, “aris<strong>in</strong>g from thedifference <strong>in</strong> effective power associated with particular cultural mean<strong>in</strong>gs and practices”(Escobar, 2008: 14).<strong>The</strong> entic<strong>in</strong>g power <strong>of</strong> these government tactics aimed at <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g specific populations withdist<strong>in</strong>ctive worldviews, which sometimes may not comply with the extractivist developmentbandwagon’s pr<strong>in</strong>ciples, is augmented by on-field charismatic agents work<strong>in</strong>g for the flex-cropagribus<strong>in</strong>esses. <strong>The</strong>se are known as ‘coyotes’, who due to their local recognition 30 are able topervade the communal government <strong>in</strong>stitutions to dispute the symbolic power underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gdom<strong>in</strong>ant knowledge and practices (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g customs) <strong>in</strong> the community (Bourdieu, 1994:163,Ishihara and Pascual, 2009). <strong>The</strong>se corporate coyotes do not act <strong>in</strong> a vacuum, though. <strong>The</strong>ymach<strong>in</strong>ate on the new possibilities for community class, gender, and generational power rifts30 <strong>The</strong>y <strong>in</strong>clude a wide range <strong>of</strong> actors such as NGO employees, preacher men, teachers, doctors, communityleaders, local radio stations, traditional estates’ landlords/patrons, ranchers, mayors, government <strong>of</strong>ficials, and so on.22
(potentially) emerg<strong>in</strong>g from chang<strong>in</strong>g social and property relations. <strong>The</strong>y elaborate on collectiveand <strong>in</strong>dividual concerns around land unproductivity and grow<strong>in</strong>g scarcity/price, lack <strong>of</strong> wagework opportunities, the backwardness and drudgery <strong>of</strong> peasant farm<strong>in</strong>g, or the children’suncerta<strong>in</strong> future to set the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses up as a new development messiah. <strong>The</strong>y seek,<strong>in</strong> a nutshell, to conduct conducts for different subjects <strong>in</strong> the community to will<strong>in</strong>gly behave andgovern themselves and others <strong>in</strong> conformity with the cultural and symbolic mean<strong>in</strong>gs, as well aswith the social practices, functional to the new extractivist political economy <strong>in</strong> the doma<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong>“economy, ecology, personhood, body, knowledge, property, and so forth” (Escobar, 2008:14).Coyotes are supported <strong>in</strong> their ideologiz<strong>in</strong>g and symbolic struggle by strong corporate<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> social communication (through different mass-media and <strong>in</strong> Q’eqchi’ language)and by an expectation-ris<strong>in</strong>g discourse on corporate social and ecological responsibility. Very<strong>of</strong>ten, the mean<strong>in</strong>gs and practices promoted through these bunch <strong>of</strong> dom<strong>in</strong>ant government tacticstake center stage <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’s northern lowlands because “they co<strong>in</strong>cide with the greaterpolitical power and have a hegemonic advantage [and thus] a preem<strong>in</strong>ent position <strong>in</strong> craft<strong>in</strong>gemergent dom<strong>in</strong>ant traditions” (Sivaramakrishnan, 2005: 350).As we will discuss subsequently, the successful realization <strong>of</strong> the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses’preem<strong>in</strong>ent hegemonic advantage is neither automatic, nor l<strong>in</strong>ear and <strong>in</strong> no way uncontested. It ismediated by economic and cultural distribution conflicts <strong>in</strong> different geographical scales, andsubject to reflexive adjustments and unexpected twists through time. In fact, when entic<strong>in</strong>gtactics are <strong>in</strong>sufficient to make subjects behav<strong>in</strong>g as they should, coercion comes <strong>in</strong>to play. As Liargues, “more authoritarian forms <strong>of</strong> government are <strong>of</strong>ten reserved for sections <strong>of</strong> a populationdeemed especially deficient and unable to exercise the responsibility <strong>of</strong> freedom” (2005:387,stressed added). As we keep on argu<strong>in</strong>g, the new extractivist government rationality builds onprevious ones. Thus, some <strong>of</strong> the old labor and population control mechanisms particular tocolonialism and to traditional landed upper classes’ estates are dismissed nowadays (like thecolonato regime and its patron-client relations) while others rema<strong>in</strong> (like coercion andthreaten<strong>in</strong>g). Estate, private and parastatal 31 violence is, therefore, also constitutive <strong>of</strong> themultiple logics <strong>of</strong> power steer<strong>in</strong>g the sugarcane and oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses’ <strong>in</strong>vestment strategy.Those resist<strong>in</strong>g to entic<strong>in</strong>g, legal dispossession tactics, or those <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> struggles forrepossession or access to land resources (see below) are subject to <strong>in</strong>timidation, threaten<strong>in</strong>g andaggression. This is done through a series <strong>of</strong> means, namely the enclosure <strong>of</strong> non-sell<strong>in</strong>g peasants’land with<strong>in</strong> flex-crop plantations; harassment <strong>of</strong> those refus<strong>in</strong>g to sell their land at the nonnegotiableprices; impediment <strong>of</strong> the right <strong>of</strong> way (even to government <strong>of</strong>ficials); and thecrim<strong>in</strong>alization <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous and peasant struggles through the legal prosecution <strong>of</strong> leaders andviolent evictions by state security forces and/or private and parastatal ones.Discontents and struggles for a different life projectConducts are more difficult to conduct when the material bases <strong>of</strong> exploitation and the politicaland cultural practices <strong>of</strong> dom<strong>in</strong>ance are perceived as erosive <strong>of</strong> ‘subsistence m<strong>in</strong>imums’ (Scott1976:35). Figure 8 below shows how most Q’eqchi’ male heads-<strong>of</strong>-household from the northern31 For <strong>in</strong>stance, beyond Colombian eng<strong>in</strong>eers employed by many oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses other private Colombian‘agents’ were reported to be operat<strong>in</strong>g together with <strong>Guatemala</strong>ns, and especially <strong>in</strong> the department <strong>of</strong> Petén, tocoerce peasant families and communities to accept the land deals (Alonso-Fradejas et al. 2008, Hurtado 2008).23
lowlands, no matter whether work<strong>in</strong>g for an oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>ess or not, and especially womenacross different types <strong>of</strong> household, believed that both family and community livelihoodconditions had either rema<strong>in</strong> the same or worsened after the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses’ arrival.Figure 8: Differentiated perceptions <strong>of</strong> change <strong>in</strong> livelihood conditions <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands,year 2010.80%70%60%50%40%30%20%10%0%Family improved Family worsen Family no change CommunityimprovedCommunityworsenCommunity nochangeMale plantation labourersFemale partners <strong>of</strong> plantation labourersMale NO plantation labourersFemale partners <strong>of</strong> NO plantation labourersSource: Alonso-Fradejas et al., 2011: 80.<strong>The</strong>se perceptions emerge from historically constituted subsistence levels which for the Q’eqchi’peoples from the northern lowlands are generally enrooted <strong>in</strong> recent experiences as immigrantmiddle-peasants settl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> self-organized communities as well as <strong>in</strong> not faraway memories <strong>of</strong>life under colonato regime <strong>in</strong> traditional estates. Indeed, still by 2010 around 30% <strong>of</strong> the totalfemale heads-<strong>of</strong>-household (45.7 years old on average) and 40% <strong>of</strong> the male ones (48.3 years oldon average) had born under the traditional estates’ colonato regime (Alonso-Fradejas et al., 2011:149). In this regards, many elder Q’eqchi’ participants <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual and group <strong>in</strong>terviewsconverge <strong>in</strong> stress<strong>in</strong>g that even though conditions under colonato labor regime <strong>in</strong> traditionalestates where exploitative and <strong>of</strong>ten humiliat<strong>in</strong>g, they still allowed for negotiat<strong>in</strong>g with thepatron the m<strong>in</strong>imum standards for the biological reproduction <strong>of</strong> the family. Under the dom<strong>in</strong>anthyper-commodified, outsourced and more impersonal flexible labor regime, it is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>glydifficult to negotiate even these survival m<strong>in</strong>imums. As a focus group participant stated: “before,the rich people killed us with guns, today they allow us to starve to death” (quoted <strong>in</strong> Alonso-Fradejas et al., 2008: 162).Of course, subsistence m<strong>in</strong>imums are not only historically constituted but also sociallydifferentiated. We mentioned before how peasant families showed not only higher expectationsbut also higher satisfaction levels <strong>of</strong> their consumption needs <strong>in</strong> comparison to those <strong>of</strong>(near)landless agricultural laborers. Q’eqchi’ women tend to <strong>in</strong>clude hous<strong>in</strong>g, culturallyappropriate education and land as subsistence m<strong>in</strong>imum. And subsistence m<strong>in</strong>imums forQ’eqchi’ youngsters, generally born free from colonato regime relations, tend to sp<strong>in</strong> around24
more urbanized consumption needs and imag<strong>in</strong>aries. <strong>The</strong>se socially differentiated subsistencem<strong>in</strong>imums lead to diverse standpo<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> the economic and cultural distribution conflicts fuelledby the agribus<strong>in</strong>esses’ land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g. For <strong>in</strong>stance, most <strong>of</strong> the surveyed (near)landless,male heads-<strong>of</strong>-household (even those work<strong>in</strong>g for a flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>ess) oppose to theexpansion <strong>of</strong> the labor-expell<strong>in</strong>g, flex-crop plantations which <strong>in</strong> addition complicate theirabilities to farm (<strong>in</strong> leased or borrowed land), and <strong>in</strong>deed to access to land one day. Q’eqchi’male youth, nonetheless, <strong>of</strong>ten embraces the ‘fast money’ and consumption status <strong>of</strong>fered by theflex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses as a way to escape from their parent’s ‘backwardness’. Even so, manyyoungsters dissent from the extractivist development path and mobilize for a future asautonomous peasants or non-agricultural labor liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a healthy ecological milieu. F<strong>in</strong>ally,Q’eqchi’ women from different classes <strong>of</strong> labor and generations are the most active groupmobiliz<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>st their partners’, fathers’, or community’s participation <strong>in</strong> land deals with flexcropagribus<strong>in</strong>esses. While cases are known where particular women have hidden the land titleaway from their partners to avoid them sell<strong>in</strong>g the land, women normally act as a collectivesubject. <strong>The</strong>y jo<strong>in</strong> forces to subvert gendered hierarchies <strong>in</strong> community government <strong>in</strong>stitutions,where they stand very <strong>of</strong>ten among the clearest and loudest voices aga<strong>in</strong>st corporate coyotes <strong>in</strong>the cultural and symbolic power struggle.On the whole, then, entic<strong>in</strong>g and coercive dom<strong>in</strong>ant government tactics, together with sociallydifferentiated perceptions <strong>of</strong> the way and extent to which subsistence security is materially,culturally and symbolically violated, pr<strong>of</strong>oundly shape the politics <strong>of</strong> land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g. Inthis context, placed-based, everyday practices <strong>of</strong> resistance (Scott, 1985; Kerkvliet, 2009) to theextractivist political economy and dom<strong>in</strong>ant government rationality <strong>in</strong>tertw<strong>in</strong>e with advocacypolitics <strong>in</strong> the economic, ecologic, cultural and political doma<strong>in</strong>s to advance a different lifeproject.On the one hand, there are many Q’eqchi’ (but also non-<strong>in</strong>digenous) peasant communities <strong>in</strong> thenorthern lowlands try<strong>in</strong>g to resist legal dispossession mechanisms by overrul<strong>in</strong>g state-endorsed<strong>in</strong>dividual freehold land ownership through the prohibition <strong>of</strong> any land deals with ranchers orcorporate agents. A communal deed <strong>of</strong>ten serves as a transcript to ‘formalize’ the agreement andto make it legible for community outsiders. In other cases, communal government <strong>in</strong>stitutionsrule the on-go<strong>in</strong>g process <strong>of</strong> legalized dispossession by prevent<strong>in</strong>g community members fromborrow<strong>in</strong>g land or giv<strong>in</strong>g it on lease to those who sold their land to a rancher or to a corporateagent without a reason properly sanctioned under dom<strong>in</strong>ant community knowledge and practices.Other similar practices <strong>in</strong>clude that <strong>of</strong> not accept<strong>in</strong>g as a new community member anyone knownto have voluntarily sold his or her land previously, and that <strong>of</strong> expell<strong>in</strong>g from the communityanyone who violates the non-sell<strong>in</strong>g communal agreement. This counter-rul<strong>in</strong>g is seldomeffective <strong>in</strong> steer<strong>in</strong>g the conduct <strong>of</strong> communitarians with state-endorsed, <strong>in</strong>dividual freeholdrights over a land plot when aforementioned reasons for peasants to engage <strong>in</strong> land deals areaddressed. Thus, very <strong>of</strong>ten struggles aga<strong>in</strong>st dispossession converge on the need to strengthenand <strong>in</strong>tensify a family and community-controlled, agroecological and/or low-external-<strong>in</strong>putbasedagricultural model. With a f<strong>in</strong>ancially weakened (and usually politically unwill<strong>in</strong>g) state tosupport this strategy, ‘Campes<strong>in</strong>o a Campes<strong>in</strong>o’ (Farmer to Farmer, see Holt-Giménez 2006)agroecological knowledge exchanges are carried out with support from rural social movements,NGOs, the Social Pastoral <strong>of</strong> the Catholic Church, and some scholars and local state <strong>of</strong>ficials.25
Besides, two regional, self-organized ‘peasant markets’ (where non-peasant merchants are notallowed) run twice a week <strong>in</strong> the villages <strong>of</strong> Chisec and Raxruhá (both near to important nationalroads). In the face <strong>of</strong> grow<strong>in</strong>g obstacles for migration <strong>in</strong> search <strong>of</strong> new farm land to rema<strong>in</strong> afeasible escape valve (as <strong>in</strong> previous historical junctures), secur<strong>in</strong>g a place-based livelihood isconsidered as a fundamental means towards ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g access to land and secur<strong>in</strong>g it fromdispossession.On the other hand, “specific modes <strong>of</strong> resistance (especially when they are cloaked <strong>in</strong> theapparent <strong>in</strong>nocuousness <strong>of</strong> ‘everyday forms’) are effective only <strong>in</strong> relation to particular forms <strong>of</strong>dom<strong>in</strong>ation” (Sivaramakrishnan, 2005: 351). With<strong>in</strong> current political dynamics <strong>of</strong> change <strong>in</strong>land-based social relations the ameliorat<strong>in</strong>g impact <strong>of</strong> everyday practices <strong>of</strong> resistance is<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly lessened by clos<strong>in</strong>g and/or narrow<strong>in</strong>g possibilities for moral-economic negotiationson subsistence m<strong>in</strong>imums. Thus, we argue that the new dom<strong>in</strong>ant government rationality,impersonal as the neoliberal one yet pervasive <strong>in</strong> daily life as the colonialist, has<strong>in</strong>cubated/prompted a demobiliz<strong>in</strong>g epistemic rift which is nonetheless turn<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>st itself. Ithas pushed the economic and cultural distribution conflicts so far that entic<strong>in</strong>g tactics arenormally <strong>in</strong>sufficient to handle them and coercive and discipl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g ones are becom<strong>in</strong>g too usual.<strong>The</strong> new dom<strong>in</strong>ant government rationality has been so far <strong>in</strong>capable <strong>of</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g past and recentagrarian and environmental conflicts abound<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Guatemala</strong>n countryside (see figure 9below), especially <strong>in</strong> the territories targeted by the new extractivist politico-economic <strong>in</strong>terests.Figure 9: Location <strong>of</strong> the 1,288 agrarian and environmental conflicts registered by the Government<strong>of</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> <strong>in</strong> 2011Target territories foroil palm, sugarcane,m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, oilextraction, bighydroelectric damsand convervationenclosuresScale: 1:3,000,000Green dots refer to open conflicts and redones to conflicts resolved and/or closedSource: Based on Government <strong>of</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> (http://portal.saa.gob.gt/ accessed on 25 June 2012).<strong>The</strong>refore, many conducts are conducted accord<strong>in</strong>g to plans, but many others are not. On thecontrary, resistance to land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g is be<strong>in</strong>g framed <strong>in</strong> many occasions as part <strong>of</strong> a morestrategic engagement <strong>in</strong> advocacy politics for a different, Q’eqchi’ life project. Practices <strong>of</strong>26
esistance are framed with<strong>in</strong> the (strategically essentialist) collective identity <strong>of</strong> Q’eqchi’ peoplesas R’al Ch’och (‘Sons and Daughters <strong>of</strong> the Earth’, who live <strong>of</strong>f and care for Mother Earth whoreciprocally cares for them).Q’eqchi’ people from different classes <strong>of</strong> labor, genders, generations and villages are mobiliz<strong>in</strong>garound the powerfully ideologiz<strong>in</strong>g collective identity as R’al Ch’och. It is from this mobiliz<strong>in</strong>gdiscourse that struggles to defend access to and control over territorial land resources areembedded <strong>in</strong> the wider claim to govern land resources and populations under a different, nonextractivistrationale. Even if claims are generally made build<strong>in</strong>g on this identity- and classrelatedstandpo<strong>in</strong>t this dynamic is not to be romanticized, though. Both the character and the pathtowards this ‘different life project’ are highly contested even among different Q’eqchi’ socialgroups (especially from women’s and youngsters’). What appears to be a common and recentstrategy, nevertheless, is that claims from different grassroots organizations and groups areaddressed to the state and the agribus<strong>in</strong>esses through a more dynamic engagement with militantrural social movements and allies.With<strong>in</strong> this non-unproblematic <strong>in</strong>teraction (<strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> objectives, agendas, mobiliz<strong>in</strong>g discourseand even personal egos), different Q’eqchi’ groups and grassroots organizations considerengag<strong>in</strong>g more actively with structured rural social movements and their allies (<strong>of</strong>ten l<strong>in</strong>ked tonational, Lat<strong>in</strong> American and global networks), as a tactic to augment the political impact <strong>of</strong>their collective action beyond the local fronts. This is done, especially, when support is needed <strong>in</strong>the realms <strong>of</strong> land occupations, labor claims, and juridical litigation and campaign<strong>in</strong>g 32 . In turn,place-based Q’eqchi’ practices <strong>of</strong> resistance <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands allow for the relocalizationand base-amplification <strong>of</strong> militant rural social movements. Many <strong>of</strong> these historical <strong>in</strong>digenous,peasant, women and rural laborers social movements resulted somehow detached from territorialpractices <strong>of</strong> resistance after their commitment to energy-consum<strong>in</strong>g (and many times divisiveand bureaucratiz<strong>in</strong>g) struggles <strong>in</strong> the national and <strong>in</strong>ternational arenas dur<strong>in</strong>g the last twodecades 33 . Furthermore, place-based Q’eqchi’ practices <strong>of</strong> resistance, together with those <strong>of</strong> other<strong>in</strong>digenous and lad<strong>in</strong>o peoples’ <strong>in</strong> the western highlands and the eastern region <strong>in</strong> the face <strong>of</strong> thenew extractivist political economy, provides many historical social movements with reneweddiscursive formations. It is <strong>in</strong> this way that, for example, class-based struggles for redistributiveland reform are augmented by more <strong>in</strong>tersectional and strategic struggles <strong>in</strong> defense <strong>of</strong> theterritory sometimes aimed at develop<strong>in</strong>g different, non-compliant with the dom<strong>in</strong>ant extractivistgovernment rationality, territorial life projects.32 <strong>The</strong>se practices are very <strong>of</strong>ten crim<strong>in</strong>alized and violently suppressed. Dissent<strong>in</strong>g Q’eqchi’ rural dwellers arecensored as anti-developmentalist and prosecuted as part <strong>of</strong> anti-‘rule <strong>of</strong> law’, social order destabiliz<strong>in</strong>g groups.33 From 1986 when the first civilian government s<strong>in</strong>ce 1954 was ‘democratically’ elected, and previously to andespecially after the 1996 Peace Agreements, (rural) social movements emerged from underground work to theforefront <strong>of</strong> democratization struggles. <strong>The</strong>se militant movements have been actively engaged <strong>in</strong> national and<strong>in</strong>ternational advocacy politics with regards to the impacts <strong>of</strong> economic liberalization over peasant economies andrural life <strong>in</strong> general. <strong>The</strong>y have been challeng<strong>in</strong>g the neoliberal corporate food regime orchestrated at the WorldTrade Organization, <strong>in</strong>tended to be pushed forward by the (failed) Free Trade Agreement <strong>of</strong> the Americas andf<strong>in</strong>ally enforced through regional Free Trade Agreements such as the (DR-CAFTA) with the USA or the AssociationAgreement with the European Union. On (rural) social movements <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong> from the 1980s, see: Bastos andCamus, 2003; Brett, 2006; Macleod Howland, 2008; and Edelman, 2008.27
Conclusions<strong>Land</strong> control grabb<strong>in</strong>g by sugarcane and oil palm agribus<strong>in</strong>esses is a means and an effect <strong>of</strong> anew extractivist political economy orchestrated from the very core <strong>of</strong> the oligarchic, yettransnationalized, post-colonial power <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>. This new extractivist political economy,conceived and unfolded through complementary political and economic logics <strong>of</strong> power <strong>in</strong>capitalism, is anchored and steered from a dist<strong>in</strong>ctive dom<strong>in</strong>ant government rationalitydelegitimiz<strong>in</strong>g non-compliant economic, political, ecologic and cultural practices.Under this extractivist rationale, different land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms are unfold<strong>in</strong>g bythese flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses with the purposes <strong>of</strong> controll<strong>in</strong>g land and natural resources as wellas land-based wealth and the (m<strong>in</strong>imal) labor to produce it. Different land deals result <strong>in</strong> differentdirections <strong>of</strong> change <strong>in</strong> land use, property relations, and labor regimes, which reassign controlover local, agricultural land-based wealth. Previous neoliberal land reform, land titl<strong>in</strong>g, andagricultural policy and political economy environment strategically enabled currentagribus<strong>in</strong>esses’ <strong>in</strong>vestment strategy. As a result <strong>of</strong> this <strong>in</strong>vestment strategy land is be<strong>in</strong>g(re)concentrated but most dispossessed <strong>in</strong>digenous-peasant families received a payment for theirland which neither allowed them to boost a non-farm livelihood, nor to rega<strong>in</strong> land ownershipelsewhere as land prices keep ris<strong>in</strong>g. <strong>The</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> peasant <strong>in</strong>corporation to the contract-farm<strong>in</strong>gprogramme among middle peasants, the oil palm <strong>in</strong>dustry and the government are troublesome.And labor processes and associated work<strong>in</strong>g conditions with<strong>in</strong> the flexibilized labor regime <strong>in</strong>the plantations are not only destroy<strong>in</strong>g other local forms <strong>of</strong> employment, but also putt<strong>in</strong>g higherpressure on children’s and women’s unpaid labor while erod<strong>in</strong>g the abilities <strong>of</strong> the plantationworkers to work on their own farms. Indeed, the widespread<strong>in</strong>g flexible labor regime furthertensions the problematic agrarian question <strong>of</strong> labor <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>.Chang<strong>in</strong>g social and property relations <strong>in</strong> the northern lowlands have resulted <strong>in</strong> both, moreheterogeneous class formations and more complex <strong>in</strong>ter- and <strong>in</strong>tra-class relations. Flex-cropagribus<strong>in</strong>esses have become dom<strong>in</strong>ant over traditional landed upper classes and territorialpolitical elites. <strong>The</strong> previously rather homogeneous middle peasantry is splitt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to diverserural classes <strong>of</strong> labor. Furthermore, previously patron-client relations <strong>of</strong> production <strong>in</strong> traditionalestates fall beh<strong>in</strong>d the hyper-commodified labor regime <strong>of</strong> the flex-crop agribus<strong>in</strong>esses,controlled by distant oligarchs and shareholders. Thus, cultural, political and symbolicalcommand becomes essential to support conditions for accumulation and economic rul<strong>in</strong>g overplace-based resources and populations.On the whole, the politics <strong>of</strong> land control grabb<strong>in</strong>g are pr<strong>of</strong>oundly shaped by both, entic<strong>in</strong>g andcoercive dom<strong>in</strong>ant government tactics, as well as by socially differentiated perceptions <strong>of</strong> theway and extent to which subsistence security is violated. In many cases, placed-based everydaypractices <strong>of</strong> resistance <strong>in</strong>tertw<strong>in</strong>e with advocacy politics <strong>in</strong> the economic, ecologic, cultural andpolitical doma<strong>in</strong>s to advance a different life project. Many Q’eqchi’ peasant communities try toresist legal dispossession mechanisms by overrul<strong>in</strong>g state-endorsed <strong>in</strong>dividual freehold landownership through the prohibition <strong>of</strong> any land deals with ranchers or corporate agents. Thiscounter-rul<strong>in</strong>g has been more effective when a family and community-controlled susta<strong>in</strong>ablesmall-scale farm<strong>in</strong>g and market<strong>in</strong>g model was concurrently developed or strengthened. In theface <strong>of</strong> grow<strong>in</strong>g obstacles for farm land migration to rema<strong>in</strong> a feasible escape valve, secur<strong>in</strong>g a28
place-based livelihood has become a fundamental means towards ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g access to land andsecur<strong>in</strong>g it from dispossession.But most dist<strong>in</strong>ctively, Q’eqchi’ people from different classes <strong>of</strong> labor, genders, generations andvillages are mobiliz<strong>in</strong>g around the non-unproblematic, but powerfully ideologiz<strong>in</strong>g, collectiveidentity as R’al Ch’och. It is from this mobiliz<strong>in</strong>g discourse that struggles to defend access to andcontrol over territorial land resources are embedded <strong>in</strong> the wider claim to govern land resourcesand populations under a different, non-extractivist rationale. Q’eqchi’ groups and grassrootsorganizations search for a more dynamic engagement with militant rural social movements as atactic to gather support, and augment the political impact <strong>of</strong> their struggle beyond the localfronts. Though also non tension-free, this tactic has been considered a mutually beneficial andlearn<strong>in</strong>g experience. Q’eqchi’ and other <strong>Guatemala</strong>n peoples’ place-based practices <strong>of</strong> resistanceallow for the relocalization and base-amplification <strong>of</strong> militant rural social movements, as well asfor an <strong>in</strong>tersectional mobiliz<strong>in</strong>g discourse and a more comprehensive claim for different lifeprojects.ReferencesAlonso-Fradejas, A., J.L. Caal Hub, and T. Miranda Ch<strong>in</strong>chilla (2011) Plantaciones Agro<strong>in</strong>dustriales,Dom<strong>in</strong>ación y Despojo Indígena-campes<strong>in</strong>o en la <strong>Guatemala</strong> del Siglo XXI. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: IDEAR-CONGCOOP.Alonso-Fradejas, A., F. Alonzo, and J. Dürr (2008) Caña de Azúcar y Palma Africana: Combustiblespara un Nuevo Ciclo de Acumulación y Dom<strong>in</strong>io en <strong>Guatemala</strong>. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: IDEAR-CONGCOOP,APRODEV, CIDSE, CIFCA, FIAN and Vía Campes<strong>in</strong>a (2011) El Derecho a la Alimentación y laSituación de Defensoras y Defensores de Derechos Humanos en <strong>Guatemala</strong>. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: MagnaTerra.Araghi, F. (2009) ‘<strong>The</strong> Invisible Hand and the Visible Foot: Peasants, Dispossession and <strong>Global</strong>ization’,en A. H. Akram-Lodhi y Cristobal Kay (eds.) Peasants and <strong>Global</strong>ization: Political Economy,Rural Transformation and the Agrarian Question. London: Routledge.Arrighi, G. (1994). <strong>The</strong> long twentieth century: Money, power, and the orig<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> our times. London:Verso.Bastos, S. and Camus, M. (2003) Entre el Mecapal y el Cielo: Desarrollo del Movimiento Maya en<strong>Guatemala</strong>. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: FLACSO-Cholsamaj.Bernste<strong>in</strong>, H. (2010a) Class Dynamics <strong>of</strong> Agrarian Change. Halifax: Fernwood.Bernste<strong>in</strong>, H. (2010b) ‘Rural Livelihoods and Agrarian Change: Br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g Class Back <strong>in</strong>’, <strong>in</strong> Long, N.,J<strong>in</strong>gzhong, Y., and Yihuan, W. (eds) Rural Transformations and Development- Ch<strong>in</strong>a <strong>in</strong> Context,pp.79-109. U.K: EE Publish<strong>in</strong>g.Borras, S. Jr, J. C. Franco, S. Gómez, C. Kay and M. Spoor (2012) ‘<strong>Land</strong> <strong>Grabb<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America andthe Caribbean’, Journal <strong>of</strong> Peasant Studies 39(3) forthcom<strong>in</strong>g.Bourdieu, P. (1994) Language and Symbolic Power, Oxford: Polity Press.Bourdieu, P. (1986) ‘Social Space and Symbolic Power’, lecture delivered at the University <strong>of</strong> California,San Diego.Brett, R. (2006) Movimiento social, etnicidad y democratización en <strong>Guatemala</strong> 1985-1996, <strong>Guatemala</strong>:F&G editores.Cambranes, Julio. C., ed. (1992) 500 años de lucha por la tierra. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: FLACSO.29
Chayanov, A.V. (1966 [1925]) ‘Peasant farm Organization’ <strong>in</strong> Thorner, D., Kerblay B. and Smith R.E.F(eds.) A.V Chayanov on the <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Peasant Economy. Manchester: Manchester UniversityPress.Deere, C. D., and A. de Janvry (1979) ‘A Conceptual Framework for the Empirical Analysis <strong>of</strong> Peasants’.Giann<strong>in</strong>i Foundation Paper No. 535.De<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ger, K., D. Byerlee, J. L<strong>in</strong>dsay, A. Norton, H. Selod, and M. Stickler (2011) Ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Global</strong> Interest<strong>in</strong> Farmland: Can it Yield Susta<strong>in</strong>able and Equitable Benefits? Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC: World Bank.Du Toit, A. (2004) “‘Social Exclusion’ Discourse and Chronic Poverty: A South African Case Study”,Development and Change vol. 35, no. 5:987–1010Dürr, J. (2011) ‘Diez mitos y realidades sobre las cadenas agroalimentarias en <strong>Guatemala</strong>, y una cuentanacional de base agraria’, GIZ-CONGCOOP/IDEAR Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper. <strong>Guatemala</strong>.ECLAC (2006) Foreign Direct Investment <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America and the Caribbean <strong>in</strong> 2005. Santiago:Economic Commission for Lat<strong>in</strong> America and the Caribbean.Edelman, M. (2008) “Transnational Organiz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Agrarian Central America: Histories, Challenges,Prospects”, Journal <strong>of</strong> Agrarian Change, 8(2 & 3): 229-257.Foucault, M. (1991 [1979]) ‘Governmentality’ <strong>in</strong> Burchell, G., Gordon, C. & Miller, P. (eds.) 1991, <strong>The</strong>Foucault effect: Studies <strong>in</strong> Governmentality, London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Garoz, B., A. Alonso-Fradejas and S. Gauster (2005) Balance de la aplicación de la política agaria delBanco Mundial en <strong>Guatemala</strong>: 1996 – 2005, <strong>Guatemala</strong>: IDEAR-CONGCOOP.Gauster, S. and S. R. Isakson (2007) “Elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g Market Distortions, Perpetuat<strong>in</strong>g Rural Inequality: AnEvaluation <strong>of</strong> Market-Assisted <strong>Land</strong> Reform <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>”, Third World Quarterly, 28(8): 1519-1536.Gordon, C. (1991) ‘Governmental Rationality: An Introduction’ <strong>in</strong> Burchell, G., Gordon, C. & Miller, P.(eds.) <strong>The</strong> Foucault effect: Studies <strong>in</strong> Governmentality, London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Grandia, L. (2009) Tz´aptz´ooqeb´. El despojo recurrente al pueblo q’eqchi’. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: AVANCSO.Grünberg, G. (2003) Tierras y Territorios Indígenas en <strong>Guatemala</strong>. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: FLACSO,MINUGUA, CONTIERRA.Harvey, D. (2003) <strong>The</strong> New Imperialism. New York: Oxford University Press.Harvey, D. (2005) A Brief History <strong>of</strong> Neoliberalism. New York: Oxford University Press.Holt-Giménez, E. (2006) Campes<strong>in</strong>o a Campes<strong>in</strong>o, Voices from Lat<strong>in</strong> America, Farmer to FarmerMovement for Susta<strong>in</strong>able Agriculture. Oakland: Food First Books.Holt-Giménez, E. (2008) ‘Territorial Restructur<strong>in</strong>g and the Ground<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> Agrarian Reform: IndigenousCommunities, Gold M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and the World Bank’, TNI <strong>Land</strong> Policy Papers Series 3. Amsterdam:Transnational Institute.Hurtado, L. (2008) D<strong>in</strong>ámicas Agrarias y Reproducción Campes<strong>in</strong>a en la <strong>Global</strong>ización. El Caso de laAlta Verapaz. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: F&G Editores.Hurtado, L, and G. Sánchez (2011) ¿Qué Tipo de Empleo Ofrecen las Empresas Palmeras en elMunicipio de Sayaxché, Petén? <strong>Guatemala</strong>: Action Aid.ICEFI-UNICEF (2012) Protegiendo la nueva cosecha. Un análisis del costo para erradicar el hambre en<strong>Guatemala</strong> 2012-2021. UNICEF: <strong>Guatemala</strong>.Inter-American Comission on Human Rights (2010) ‘Medidas cautelares dictando la suspensión de laactividades de Goldcorp/Montana Exploradora S. A’. 5/4/2010-AA-50002166, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C.Ishihara, H. and U. Pascual (2009) ‘Social Capital <strong>in</strong> Community Level Environmental Governance: ACritique’, Ecological Economics 68(5):1549-1562.Kerkvliet, B. J. T. (2009) ‘Everyday politics <strong>in</strong> peasant societies (and ours)’, Journal <strong>of</strong> Peasant Studies36(1):227-243.Lahiff, E., S.M. Borras Jr. and C. Kay (2007) ‘Market-Led Agrarian Reform: Policies, Performance andProspects’, Third World Quarterly 28/8.Li, T.M. (2007) ‘Governmentality’, Anthropologica 49:275-281Li, T.M. (2005) ‘Beyond “the State” and Failed Schemes’, American Anthropologist 107(3): 383–39430
Macleod Howland, M. (2008) ‘Luchas Político Culturales y Auto-Representación Maya en <strong>Guatemala</strong>’,PhD <strong>The</strong>sis. Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México.McMichael, P. (2012) ‘<strong>The</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Grab and Corporate Food Regime Restructur<strong>in</strong>g’, Journal <strong>of</strong> PeasantStudies 39(3-4): 681-701.M<strong>in</strong>gorría, S., and G. Gamboa (2010) Metabolismo Socio-Ecológico de Hogares y ComunidadesCampes<strong>in</strong>as Q´eqchi´ en un Contexto de Expansión de la Agro-<strong>in</strong>dustria de la Caña de Azúcar yla Palma Africana: El Caso del Valle del Río Polochic. <strong>Guatemala</strong>. <strong>Guatemala</strong>: ICTA-UAB/IDEAR-CONGCOOP.OHCHR (2012) ‘Report <strong>of</strong> the United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights on the Activities <strong>of</strong>Her Office <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’. Genève: A/HRC/19/21/Add.1Peluso, N.L. and C. Lund (2011) ‘New frontiers <strong>of</strong> land control: Introduction’, Journal <strong>of</strong> Peasant Studies38(4):667-681Ribot, J.C, and Peluso, N.L (2003) “A theory <strong>of</strong> Access”, Rural Sociology June 68(2).Scott, J. C. (1976) <strong>The</strong> Moral Economy <strong>of</strong> the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence <strong>in</strong> Southeast Asia. NewHaven: Yale University Press.Scott, J. C. (1985) Weapons <strong>of</strong> the Weak: Everyday Forms <strong>of</strong> Peasant Resistance. New Haven:Yale University Press.Shan<strong>in</strong>, T. (1966) ‘Chayanov’s Message: Illum<strong>in</strong>ations, Miscomprehensions, and the Contemporary“Development <strong>The</strong>ory”’ <strong>in</strong> Thorner, D., Kerblay B. and Smith R.E.F (eds.) A.V Chayanov on the<strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> Peasant Economy. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Sivaramakrishnan, K. (2005) ‘Some Intellectual Genealogies for the Concept <strong>of</strong> Everyday Resistance’,American Anthropologist 107(3): 346-355Solano, L. (2009) Estudio del Dest<strong>in</strong>o de la Producción de Caña de Azúcar y Palma Africana y laSituación de la Producción y el Mercado de Agrocombustibles en <strong>Guatemala</strong>. Action Aid.Wood, E. M. (2006) ‘Logics <strong>of</strong> Power: A Conversation with David Harvey’, Historical Materialism 14(4)9-34Wood, E. M. (2003) Empire <strong>of</strong> Capital. Second Edition, London: Verso.World Bank (2007) World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development. Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC:World Bank.Ybarra M. (2010) ‘Liv<strong>in</strong>g on Scorched Earth: <strong>The</strong> Political Ecology <strong>of</strong> <strong>Land</strong> Ownership <strong>in</strong> <strong>Guatemala</strong>’sNorthern Lowlands’, PhD <strong>The</strong>sis. University <strong>of</strong> California, Berkeley.31