Small-scale Sugarcane Growers in Mtubatuba, KwaZulu-Natal ...
Small-scale Sugarcane Growers in Mtubatuba, KwaZulu-Natal ...
Small-scale Sugarcane Growers in Mtubatuba, KwaZulu-Natal ...
Create successful ePaper yourself
Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.
List of AcronymsBICBTICEDCFCSGCTSDAEADoPDSGDTIFAF/UAFGATTGSOISAKFCLSGLZMAFISAMCCNADPSFSACGASAMASASASASRISGDTSGESIASPFSSGUCOSPUSMWTOBantu Investment CorporationBoard of Trade and IndustryCorporation for Economic DevelopmentContract/Outgrower Farm<strong>in</strong>gChild Support GrantCane Transport SystemDepartment of Agriculture and Environment AffairsDivision of ProceedsDisability GrantDepartment of Trade and IndustryF<strong>in</strong>ancial Aid Fund/Umthombo Agricultural F<strong>in</strong>anceGeneral Agreement on Tariffs and TradeGrower Support OfficerInternational Sugar Agreement<strong>KwaZulu</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ance CorporationLarge-Scale <strong>Sugarcane</strong> GrowerLoad<strong>in</strong>g ZoneMicro Agriculture F<strong>in</strong>ance Institute of South AfricaMill Cane CommitteeDepartment of Native AffairsPrice Stabilization FundSouth African Cane <strong>Growers</strong>’ AssociationSouth African Millers’ AssociationSouth African Sugar AssociationSouth African Sugar Research Institute<strong>Small</strong> Grower Development Trust<strong>Small</strong> Grower EntitlementSugar Industry AgreementSupplementary Payment Fund<strong>Small</strong>-Scale <strong>Sugarcane</strong> <strong>Growers</strong>Umfolozi Sugar Planters LtdUmfolozi Sugar MillWorld Trade Organization
estimated area of around 38,000 ha. 8 Furthermore, by 1982 representatives of <strong>KwaZulu</strong>, KaNgwane and theSouth African Millers’ Association (SAMA) were mak<strong>in</strong>g representations to government’s Rorich Commission ofInquiry to motivate for a considerable expansion <strong>in</strong> sugarcane production, about half of which was to come fromSSGs. Approximate projections had targeted an additional 33,200 ha and 6,330 ha <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong> and KaNgwanerespectively, each capable of provid<strong>in</strong>g an estimated 116,000 and 32,000 tons of sugar. 9 The ultimate expansionwas certa<strong>in</strong>ly immense: by the early 1990s, SSGs had <strong>in</strong>creased their total share of the national area under canefrom 1.3% to 20%; by 2001-2 the number of SSGs had <strong>in</strong>creased to 50,000, and their share of production haddoubled to 14%. 10However, by the mid-2000s, FAF (which had been re-dubbed Umthombo Agricultural F<strong>in</strong>ance) hadrevoked its credit offer<strong>in</strong>g facilities, cit<strong>in</strong>g widespread grower fraud and writ<strong>in</strong>g-off millions <strong>in</strong> loans. Moreover, bythe late 2000s, a terrible drought had seem<strong>in</strong>gly <strong>in</strong>stigated the widespread drop-out of SSGs and a massivedecrease <strong>in</strong> production. By 2011/12 only 13,871 registered SSGs delivered cane, produc<strong>in</strong>g 8.59% of the totalcrop. 11 This tremendous decl<strong>in</strong>e is made further curious by the fact that significant droughts <strong>in</strong> the 1980s, whileresult<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a brief and dramatic drop <strong>in</strong> production, did little to stem the tide of overall SSG growth.Understand<strong>in</strong>g why FAF/UAF was compelled to term<strong>in</strong>ate its credit services when it did and why SSG productionwas so drastically impacted by drought requires a critical exam<strong>in</strong>ation of the conventional narrative of SSGgrowth as a product of the extension of small-<strong>scale</strong> credit and characterizations of SSGs as <strong>in</strong>dependentcommercial farmers. Of central importance is the material and <strong>in</strong>stitutional articulation of FAF with mill<strong>in</strong>g capitaland the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> government, and thus as one component of a wider regime govern<strong>in</strong>g SSG production; arelationship founded with<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry’s particular regulatory structure and ultimately underm<strong>in</strong>ed by itsrestructur<strong>in</strong>g.Between State and Industry: Relocat<strong>in</strong>g FAF and SSG ProductionNotwithstand<strong>in</strong>g rhetorical commitments to ‘development’, it is important to note that the emergence of FAF and<strong>in</strong>tensified efforts to expand SSG production from 1974 was not co<strong>in</strong>cidental. From the mid to late 1960s, the<strong>in</strong>dustry had taken a calculated risk to <strong>in</strong>crease its <strong>in</strong>ternational quota under the International Sugar Agreement(ISA), witness<strong>in</strong>g a massive expansion <strong>in</strong> capital capacity and area under cane. However, the high world priceswhich had spurred these <strong>in</strong>vestments faltered, and by 1968 the <strong>in</strong>dustry was compelled to seek governmentbackedloans of R16 million to stabilize cane prices and <strong>in</strong>terest payments. 12 Nonetheless, the <strong>in</strong>dustry’s fortunesimproved follow<strong>in</strong>g the US embargo of Cuba and its consequent turn to the world market to meet consumption,which resulted <strong>in</strong> a spike <strong>in</strong> export prices <strong>in</strong> the early 1970s and generated record export earn<strong>in</strong>gs for the<strong>in</strong>dustry. 13 Emboldened by w<strong>in</strong>dfall earn<strong>in</strong>gs, millers <strong>in</strong> particular began re-awaken<strong>in</strong>g hopes of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g canesupply to meet the <strong>in</strong>creased throughput requirements of their capital <strong>in</strong>vestments. Simultaneously, however, theformation of ‘<strong>in</strong>dependent homelands’ by the apartheid state threatened to imp<strong>in</strong>ge on cane lands earmarked forconsolidation <strong>in</strong>to the Bantustans, particularly <strong>KwaZulu</strong>. Established with R5 million from the <strong>in</strong>dustry’s exportearn<strong>in</strong>gs, the orig<strong>in</strong> of FAF and efforts to <strong>in</strong>crease SSG production <strong>in</strong> 1974 was rooted largely <strong>in</strong> the miller’sambition to augment the high throughput requirements of a capital <strong>in</strong>tensive and concentrated mill<strong>in</strong>g sector at atime when cane-supply itself was threatened by the establishment of the ‘<strong>in</strong>dependent homelands’.Nonetheless, despite the precipitous decl<strong>in</strong>e of export prices throughout the mid-late 1970s, coupledwith ris<strong>in</strong>g oil prices and mount<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>flation, FAF and SSG production cont<strong>in</strong>ued to expand. However, althoughthe <strong>in</strong>dustry was content to “take credit for a large amount of the stimulus which has given rise to <strong>in</strong>creased[SSG] production’’, they admitted that “the Fund cannot claim that the total <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> production…is solely due8Rorich, A. J. V. 1982. Report of the Committee of Inquiry <strong>in</strong>to the Sugar Industry, Republic of South Africa. p.89Rorich, A. J. V. 1982. Report of the Committee of Inquiry <strong>in</strong>to the Sugar Industry p.1410Bates, R. and Sokhela, P. 2003. “The Development of <strong>Small</strong>-Scale Sugar Cane <strong>Growers</strong>: A Success Story?” p. 10711SASA. 2011/12. South African Sugar Industry Directory 2011/12. Durban. p.1312Van Biljon, F.J. 1970. Commission of <strong>in</strong>quiry Into the Sugar Industry. Republic of South Africa p.p. 913Nedbank. 1974. Sugar and the South African Sugar <strong>in</strong>dustry: A Critical Assessment. Nedsual Economic Unit: Johannesburg. p.28
to its efforts” 14 . At least some of the credit would have to be reserved for other players. One of the most notable<strong>in</strong> this regard was the ‘developmental partnership’ forged with the recently formed <strong>KwaZulu</strong> state. The mostbasic dimension of this relationship concerned legitimat<strong>in</strong>g the extension of sugar production <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong>.Previously, SSG sugarcane quotas had been held <strong>in</strong> ‘trust’ by SASA’s Central Board. However, with theestablishment of <strong>KwaZulu</strong> as the ultimate authority over ‘tribal’ tenure, SSG sugar quotas were similarlyeffectively placed with<strong>in</strong> the jurisdiction of the new ‘state’. Cooperation and liaison with the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> government<strong>in</strong> both locat<strong>in</strong>g physical grounds and negotiat<strong>in</strong>g the political terra<strong>in</strong> of tenure was thus essential, and <strong>in</strong>deedChief Sithole, act<strong>in</strong>g Executive Councillor of the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> Department of Agriculture and Forestry, along with fiveofficials from his department, were approached early to ‘assist’ <strong>in</strong> the design of FAF. 15 More directly, <strong>in</strong>itiat<strong>in</strong>gcane production <strong>in</strong> any particular area <strong>in</strong> the first <strong>in</strong>stance required approach<strong>in</strong>g and establish<strong>in</strong>g a rapport withthe local ‘tribal Inkosi’, with particular care be<strong>in</strong>g taken to assure him that neither cane production nor farmers’associations would imp<strong>in</strong>ge on his authority. As observed by Vaughan (1992a):“Because land is allocated through the tribal authorities, and it is access to the parts of this land which are suitable for cane production which is the majorconsideration for the mill<strong>in</strong>g companies wish<strong>in</strong>g to expand production, they are obliged to use these traditional structures reconstituted by the apartheidstate” 16In regards to material assistance, the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> state was similarly <strong>in</strong>volved directly from an early stage,with early references not<strong>in</strong>g the government’s <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> the construction of <strong>in</strong>frastructure and the provisionof 50 extension officers for sugarcane development. However, less pronounced <strong>in</strong> such asides was the degree ofarticulation between FAF, miller-owned ‘development’ companies, and the f<strong>in</strong>ancial arms of the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> ‘state’.As early as 1974, FAF was already seek<strong>in</strong>g ‘cooperative action’ with the Bantu Investment Corporation (BIC) <strong>in</strong>regard to develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>frastructure. 17 Itself hav<strong>in</strong>g been <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> sugar fund<strong>in</strong>g for several years, the BIC wasreplaced by the Corporation for Economic Development (CED) <strong>in</strong> 1977, but follow<strong>in</strong>g the recommendations of the1978 McCrystal Report, its duties were delegated to the new <strong>KwaZulu</strong> Development Corporation, and six yearslater, the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ance Corporation (KFC). The CED had always supported the establishment of millerowned ‘development companies’ to facilitate a ‘tripartite alliance’ between the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> Department ofAgriculture, millers and small-<strong>scale</strong> black farmers, and to this end the CED and later KFC provided soft loans forthe purposes of on-lend<strong>in</strong>g to SSGs, contractors and capital works such as the build<strong>in</strong>g of cane depots andbases. 18 Although precise figures are not available as to the extent of such f<strong>in</strong>ancial support, <strong>in</strong> 1982 the SASAchairman made a public aside on the substantive extent of contributions by the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> government and‘develop<strong>in</strong>g companies:“With regard to the back<strong>in</strong>g that the Fund receives, I must pay tribute to the tremendous role played by the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> Department of Agriculture andForestry, which together with millers and growers have provided all the <strong>in</strong>frastructure and extension services necessary for the development of sugarcanelands <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong>. It is estimated that the <strong>in</strong>frastructure provided by <strong>KwaZulu</strong> has to date matched <strong>in</strong> value the loans advanced by the Fund.” 19[emphasis added]A notable political corollary of this <strong>in</strong>tersection between the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> ‘state’ and millers was the politicalleverage it offered <strong>in</strong> negotiations with the apartheid government, and with<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry itself. For <strong>in</strong>stance,despite reservations by SASA and SACGA, representatives of both SAMA and <strong>KwaZulu</strong> successfully lobbiedgovernment’s Rorich Commission of Inquiry to endorse a strategy of expand<strong>in</strong>g cane supply largely from SSGs,largely premised on appeals made to the ‘developmental’ effects of SSG production with occasional allusions totheir wider legitimat<strong>in</strong>g impacts. 20 <strong>KwaZulu</strong> for <strong>in</strong>stance argued that a failure to expand would “cause scepticism14SASYB. 1978/9. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1978/9. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal. p.4915SASYB. 1972/3. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1972/3. p.2116Vaughan, Anne. 1992a. “Commercial Cane Production <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong>: A Modernis<strong>in</strong>g Initiative?’’ p.1417SASYB. 1974/5. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1974/5. p.5018Rahman, Shafiur. 1997. Aspects of Deregulation <strong>in</strong> the South African Sugar Industry: Implications for <strong>Small</strong> Holders. Unpublished paper. p.819SASYB. 1981/2. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1981/2. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal. p.3920Rorich, A. J. V. 1982. Report of the Committee of Inquiry <strong>in</strong>to the Sugar Industry. p.21, 24, 32
Newspaper with more than 4ha under sugarcane were able to meet basic subsistence requirements fromsugarcane earn<strong>in</strong>gs, and none did at Nqunquma. 25 With the widespread displacement of both food cropp<strong>in</strong>g andcattle graz<strong>in</strong>g, both communities thus came to become particularly dependant on a mixture of cash-<strong>in</strong>come fromsugarcane and migrant labour earn<strong>in</strong>gs, a f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g replicated by Vaughan (1991). 26A significant aspect of the production process itself found by Cobbet was that at Newspaper, a conditionof the loan f<strong>in</strong>ance was control over its use and application, effectively leav<strong>in</strong>g only the task of weed<strong>in</strong>g to theapplicant homestead. Moreover, concerns over trajectory could be <strong>in</strong>ferred by the fact that many sugarcanehomesteads <strong>in</strong> Nqunquma had found themselves <strong>in</strong> a viscous spiral of decreas<strong>in</strong>g returns, <strong>in</strong>put purchases andyields follow<strong>in</strong>g the repayment of their loan. Vaughan (1992b) similarly observed at the Sezela and Maidstonearea that a substantial proportion of cane establishment was undertaken by the mill, whereby “teams of labourersemployed by the mill weed and fertilize for growers on request” 27 , a process replicated at the level of ratoonmanagement. The attitude of the Sezela mill staff reflected this attitude, assert<strong>in</strong>g “We must stop try<strong>in</strong>g to makefarmers out of growers who own ‘postage stamps’ [<strong>in</strong>significant parcels of land]” 28 . Rather than <strong>in</strong>spir<strong>in</strong>g a classof <strong>in</strong>dependent farmers, as observed by Vaughan, “the relationship between grower and company may, <strong>in</strong> thesecases, resemble that between lessor and lessee’’ 29 . While Vaughan found a difference of attitude at the Felixtonand Amatikulu mills, where authorities stressed their “objective is to develop people not land”, it was admittedthat such attitudes were cont<strong>in</strong>gent on an “expanded and ref<strong>in</strong>ed’’ extension system, <strong>in</strong>tensified “to maximizecane supply through very close monitor<strong>in</strong>g of the production process’’ 30 . For Rahman (1997), the differences <strong>in</strong>such developmental philosophies were by and large conditioned by the relative levels of urbanization, particularlythe availability of non-agricultural employment opportunities and population pressures result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> residentialland-leas<strong>in</strong>g, or ‘shack-farm<strong>in</strong>g’, which would compel mill<strong>in</strong>g development companies to adopt as much of thedevelopment process as possible. In ‘more rural’ areas with less population pressure and fewer employmentopportunities, Rahman observed that ‘chas<strong>in</strong>g cane’ was less of a ‘military operation’ with millers perform<strong>in</strong>g littleof the physical operations themselves, and much fewer uptakes of FAF loans. 31Moreover, <strong>in</strong> many sugarcane grow<strong>in</strong>g-areas millers had purposefully sought to <strong>in</strong>troduce a new<strong>in</strong>termediary class with the encouraged emergence of small black ‘contractors’. With<strong>in</strong> a discourse of benefitt<strong>in</strong>g‘entrepreneurs’ miller development companies and/or <strong>KwaZulu</strong> development <strong>in</strong>stitutions adopted a policy ofextend<strong>in</strong>g loans for the purchase of tractors by selected <strong>in</strong>dividuals with<strong>in</strong> sugarcane grow<strong>in</strong>g areas to provideshort-haul<strong>in</strong>g and land preparation/plough<strong>in</strong>g services. Though such <strong>in</strong>itiatives pre-date the ‘rationalization’ of theCane Transport System (CTS) i.e. the removal of miller transport subsidies and ‘transport costs’ from miller costclaims on the DoP, that they ga<strong>in</strong>ed new emphasis afterwards is surely not co<strong>in</strong>cidental. In Cobbet’s study, localbus<strong>in</strong>ess elites took up the opportunity at Newspaper, creat<strong>in</strong>g cartels to control pric<strong>in</strong>g and to some extentre<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g exist<strong>in</strong>g stratification of wealth, while <strong>in</strong> Nqunquma a plethora of <strong>in</strong>itial contractors quickly went out ofbus<strong>in</strong>ess. 32 Vaughan (1992a) cited similar <strong>in</strong>stances of contractors fac<strong>in</strong>g severe difficulties <strong>in</strong> the sourc<strong>in</strong>g andmanagement of labour, equipment failure, and general disorganization. While the decision to foster this class ofblack <strong>in</strong>termediat<strong>in</strong>g contractors would often be located with<strong>in</strong> a notion of foster<strong>in</strong>g ‘employment’ opportunities,the empirical evidence suggests that small-<strong>scale</strong> contract<strong>in</strong>g was at best profitable for a small elite capable oforganiz<strong>in</strong>g to prevent competition, thus at the expense of small-holders, and at worst a economically volatile andultimately unprofitable operation. 3325Cobbett, M. 1984. “<strong>Sugarcane</strong> farm<strong>in</strong>g n <strong>KwaZulu</strong>: two communities <strong>in</strong>vestigated’’. Issue 58 of Carnegie Conference paper. SALDRU, School ofEconomics, University of Cape Town. p.1126Vaughan, A. 1991. Cane, Class and Credit: Report on Fieldwork – Glendale Mill Area. Institute for Social and Economic Research: University of Durban-Westville. p.827Vaughan, Anne. 1992b. “Options for rural restructur<strong>in</strong>g’’ <strong>in</strong> Robert Schire (ed) Wealth or Poverty? Critical Choices for South Africa. Oxford UniversityPress Southern Africa: Cape Town. p.44128Vaughan, Anne. 1992a. “Commercial Cane Production <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong>: A Modernis<strong>in</strong>g Initiative?’’ p.1329Vaughan, Anne. 1992b. “Options for rural restructur<strong>in</strong>g’’. p.42830Ibid, p.44031Shafiur. 1997. Aspects of Deregulation <strong>in</strong> the South African Sugar Industry. p.932Cobbett, M. 1984. “<strong>Sugarcane</strong> farm<strong>in</strong>g n <strong>KwaZulu</strong>: two communities <strong>in</strong>vestigated’’. p.1333Vaughan, Anne. 1992a. “Commercial Cane Production <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong>: A Modernis<strong>in</strong>g Initiative?’’. p.7
Chang<strong>in</strong>g the Rules: de-regulation and the shift<strong>in</strong>g basis of SSG productionFrom the early 1990s, however, the prevail<strong>in</strong>g regulatory system would undergo a series of critical shifts,culm<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a new Sugar Industry Agreement (SIA) <strong>in</strong> 2000. For SSGs, two changes were of particularsignificance. In the first place, the hidden regulatory mechanisms which had materially underp<strong>in</strong>ned miller’sdifferential <strong>in</strong>terest and <strong>in</strong>terventions <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> SSG production were effectively removed. Perhaps most importantly, afew weeks before South Africa enjoyed its first free elections, SACGA successfully lobbied to fundamentally alterthe DoP. The system of splitt<strong>in</strong>g total proceeds accord<strong>in</strong>g to average costs and return on capital was replacedwith a fixed proportional division between millers/ref<strong>in</strong>ers and growers (approximately 36%:64% respectively),effectively remov<strong>in</strong>g miller’s ability to claim adm<strong>in</strong>istration (or effective execution) of SSG production as claimable‘costs’. 34 35 Moreover, by 1998 the two-pool pric<strong>in</strong>g mechanism was consolidated, effectively elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g SSGproduction’s categorical claim on the higher-priced domestic market. In addition to spurr<strong>in</strong>g the 1997 closure ofthe Glendale mill which had relied on SSGs for over 40% of its supply, other millers and their ‘developmentcompanies’ were prompted to take a“’hard look’ at their small growers, their circumstances (especially grower debt levels and bad debts) and their importance to the mill concerned…the costsof development (establishment), re-plant<strong>in</strong>g and ratoon management…a procedure to manage withdrawal… [and] whether there is local capacity to providethe services formerly provided by the development companies…mills may need to subsidise contractors, transport costs etc.” 36In the second place however, from 1989 SASA removed restrictions on SSG registration, a move cemented bythe permanent removal of SASA’s powers of quantitative control <strong>in</strong> the 2000 SIA. 37 Consequently, and seem<strong>in</strong>glyparadoxically, the numbers of SSGs began to rapidly rise. No longer requir<strong>in</strong>g formal ‘<strong>Small</strong> Grower Entitlement’(SGE) to supply a nearby mill, 7,500 previously ‘illegal’ growers immediately registered, br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g the total numberof SSGs to over 30,000, <strong>in</strong>flat<strong>in</strong>g to three years later to 42,313 <strong>in</strong> 1992 and reach<strong>in</strong>g about 50,000 <strong>in</strong> 2003. 38The general dismantlement of the basis of subsidy implicitly placed a new imperative to develop newless costly mechanisms of support to a rapidly ris<strong>in</strong>g number of SSGs. Much of this responsibility now howeverfell to SACGA, with<strong>in</strong> which SSGs were now formally representationally subsumed. While the old <strong>in</strong>dustryrhetoric of SSG ‘development’ had been rendered somewhat hollow by millers’ direct <strong>in</strong>terventions <strong>in</strong> theproduction, SACGA now sought to develop ‘smart’ <strong>in</strong>stitutions to foster new levels SSG self-management and<strong>in</strong>dependence with<strong>in</strong> a more <strong>in</strong>clusive representational structure.One early such <strong>in</strong>stitution was the <strong>Small</strong> Grower Development Trust (SGDT), established <strong>in</strong> 1992 to‘‘promote economic empowerment of SSGs and…develop viable and <strong>in</strong>dependent cane grow<strong>in</strong>g communities’’.With an <strong>in</strong>itial R21.6 million provided by the <strong>in</strong>dustry, the SGDT focused largely on tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g SSGs and theirelected representatives, and fund<strong>in</strong>g the operational costs of their highest representational tier, the Mill CaneCommittee (MCC). Similarly, SACGA posted ‘Grower Support Officers’ (GSOs), <strong>in</strong> each mill supply area toprovide support on a wide range of tasks, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g facilitat<strong>in</strong>g the function<strong>in</strong>g of their representativeorganisations, coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g cane supply logistics <strong>in</strong> communal areas and conduct<strong>in</strong>g cane husbandry tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g.Extension support and credit facilities were are also re-configured to fit the new <strong>in</strong>stitutional circumstances. In1996 a new ‘partnership’ or ‘jo<strong>in</strong>t-venture’ was launched between the South African Sugar Research Institute(SASRI) and the Department of Agriculture and Environment Affairs (DAEA), and <strong>in</strong> 2001 FAF was re-launchedas Umthombo Agricultural F<strong>in</strong>ance (UAF).39 40 4134Along with the removal of price regulation, alteration to the DoP was made largely <strong>in</strong> response to disgruntlement from SACGA. At the core of ma<strong>in</strong>ly LSGdiscontentment was what seemed to be the manipulated escalation of miller average costs: millers, they contended, were fail<strong>in</strong>g to close down uneconomicmills; attribut<strong>in</strong>g development company costs as mill<strong>in</strong>g rather than grow<strong>in</strong>g costs; enjoy<strong>in</strong>g full ref<strong>in</strong>ery costs and return on capital as a first charge; andgenerally enjoyed an unfair advantage <strong>in</strong> their fixed-variable cost ratio, effectively mean<strong>in</strong>g that even <strong>in</strong> poor crop years millers would reta<strong>in</strong> a large claim on<strong>in</strong>dustry proceeds.35Rahman, Shafiur. 1997. Aspects of Deregulation <strong>in</strong> the South African Sugar Industry. p.2336Ibid, p.2337Department of Trade and Industry. 2003? A discussion document on the review of the Sugar Act. p.738Vaughan, A. and McIntosh. 1993. “State and Capital <strong>in</strong> the Regeneration of a South African Peasantry’’ Canadian Journal of African Studies, 27, 3. p.44739Eweg, M. 2009. Def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Partnerships <strong>in</strong> South African Agriculture. South African <strong>Sugarcane</strong> Research <strong>in</strong>stitute. p.740Armitage, RM,Hurley, KM and Gillitt, GG. 2009. “Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g Support Measures To <strong>Small</strong> Scale <strong>Growers</strong> And New Freehold <strong>Growers</strong>’’. p.359
These new <strong>in</strong>stitutional configurations nonetheless represented a substantial scal<strong>in</strong>g-down from priormiller support systems. While lauded for its work <strong>in</strong> relay<strong>in</strong>g varietal and agronomic lessons, as well asdispatch<strong>in</strong>g over R60 million worth of fertilizer over 8 weeks, SASRI’s jo<strong>in</strong>t venture with the DAEA rema<strong>in</strong>s undercapacitated,and does not extend to organizational oversight previously made by teams of miller sectionmanagers and extension officers. Nor can this gap be expected to be filled by even the most committed GSO,tasked with unenviable position of adopt<strong>in</strong>g responsibility for a wide range of tasks previously accomplished byentire teams of section managers, field officers, and mill and government extension officers for a larger numberof growers. Similarly, though by 2007 the SGDT had tra<strong>in</strong>ed over 20,000 SSGs, it has not been able to atta<strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ancial self-sufficiency, with SSGs contribut<strong>in</strong>g only R2 million of the R27.2 million <strong>in</strong> costs <strong>in</strong>curred <strong>in</strong> 2002. 42Perhaps most reveal<strong>in</strong>g of the <strong>in</strong>adequacy of the new <strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>in</strong>terventions was the ultimate closureof FAF/UAF’s credit services. As the adm<strong>in</strong>istration of loans and oversight over their productive application couldno-longer be entrusted to teams of mill field staff, UAF’s limited staff complement of 35 were was compelled totake a pre-emptive attitude through a more str<strong>in</strong>gent screen<strong>in</strong>g process. 43 The unfold<strong>in</strong>g new ‘flexible’ regimen ofopen registration and reduced productive oversight however, raised new critical challenges. One disquiet<strong>in</strong>gtrend was the uneven spread of production, Sokhela and Bates (2003) estimated that more than 50% of totalproduction orig<strong>in</strong>ated from only 20% of growers. 44 This was clearly closely related to a tendency of underresourced/capacitated/will<strong>in</strong>ggrowers to enter <strong>in</strong>to a number of, often ultimately conflictual, lease-holdarrangements with other better resourced growers seek<strong>in</strong>g to exceed their customary allocations. 45 46 Ofparticular concern to Umthombo, however was the grow<strong>in</strong>g tendency for fraud, whereby after receiv<strong>in</strong>g a loan agrower would submit his/her cane under a neighbour’s production code and effectively enjoy the returns withoutamortiz<strong>in</strong>g his/her debt. Despite a low default rate <strong>in</strong> the early 2000s, amidst drought and a ris<strong>in</strong>g cost-pricesqueeze the grow<strong>in</strong>g prevalence of such activities eventually compelled Umthombo to close its credit facilitiesand write off millions <strong>in</strong> unrecovered loans.Although Umthombo still offers sav<strong>in</strong>gs/retention services, the ultimate closure of its credit facilities <strong>in</strong>the wake of deregulation stands <strong>in</strong> opposition to the conventional narrative of the growth of SSG production asthe product of the extension of small-<strong>scale</strong> credit facilities. Without the extensive <strong>in</strong>tervention and oversight ofmillers <strong>in</strong> production, and the nexus of <strong>in</strong>dustry and state subsidy which supported it, FAF/UAF was suddenlyexposed to both the economic vulnerability and commercial opportunism of its targeted beneficiaries. Attempts to<strong>in</strong>stitute more open and ‘democratic’ representational <strong>in</strong>stitutions, while <strong>in</strong> many ways important and laudablemoments <strong>in</strong> their own right, however, were not a sufficient replacement for the material structural underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gsof the previous regulatory dispensation, patrimonial as it was. The massive growth of SSG production <strong>in</strong> the1990s-2000s follow<strong>in</strong>g the de-regulation of registration, itself characterised <strong>in</strong> part by prevalence of leas<strong>in</strong>gagreements and fraudulent credit practices, was thus someth<strong>in</strong>g of a ‘bubble’ not altogether different from those<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets, ultimately ‘popped’ by the harsh circumstances of drought which afflicted <strong>KwaZulu</strong>-<strong>Natal</strong> <strong>in</strong>the mid-2000s. In this sense, the critical question is less one of what were the proximal causes of the decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>SSG production, as what underp<strong>in</strong>ned their rapid growth <strong>in</strong> the first place.S<strong>in</strong>ce de-regulation, however, little official mention has been made of the rapid changes <strong>in</strong> theunderly<strong>in</strong>g structure of SSG production. Rather, the failure of SSGs themselves to atta<strong>in</strong> the ideal of commercialsugarcane production has largely been <strong>in</strong>terpreted by <strong>in</strong>dustry officials as a product of the characteristics ofSSGs themselves, particularly low-levels of literacy and numeracy, failures to adopt appropriate agronomicmethods, failure to harvest at appropriate times etc. Similar frustrations abound with local contractors further41Bates, R. and Sokhela, P. 2003. ‘’The Development of <strong>Small</strong>-Scale Sugar Cane <strong>Growers</strong>: A Success Story?’’ p.116, 11342Ibid, p.11643Ibid, p 11344Ibid, p.10945Munro, W.A. 1996. “Contract farm<strong>in</strong>g, community development and the politics of production among small-growers <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong>-<strong>Natal</strong>” Sem<strong>in</strong>ar paper 392,presented at University of the Witwatersrand. Institute for Advanced Social Research. p.1146Such arrangements would often take the form of multi-year arrangements whereby the lessee would agree to cover the expense of establish<strong>in</strong>g andma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the crop for a pre-agreed number of years, dur<strong>in</strong>g which she/he would enjoy the proceeds, after which the lessor would enjoy the returns fromthe rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g ratoons.
suffer<strong>in</strong>g from tight marg<strong>in</strong>s, frequent breakdowns, sometimes <strong>in</strong>flated pric<strong>in</strong>g and dilapidated equipment. 47 Inshort, after more than 40 years of so-called SSG ‘development’ the bulk of frustration by <strong>in</strong>dustry officials hasbeen with the seem<strong>in</strong>g failure of SSGs to actually ‘develop’ <strong>in</strong>to ideal commercial farmers.SACGA has nonetheless cont<strong>in</strong>ued to seek new <strong>in</strong>stitutional methods to encourage SSG <strong>in</strong>dependenceunder the new regulatory dispensation. One attempt has been to re-<strong>in</strong>troduce credit services with fund<strong>in</strong>g fromgovernment’s Micro Agriculture F<strong>in</strong>ance Institute of South Africa (MAFISA), for which approximately R50 millionhas been earmarked for sugarcane and of which approximately R7 million has been disbursed. In order to evadeprior fraudulent borrow<strong>in</strong>g practices, potential beneficiaries are now required to register as a cooperative, <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>ewith government’s Cooperatives Bill and present thorough bus<strong>in</strong>ess plans <strong>in</strong> order to ga<strong>in</strong> access to allocatedfunds. As production and payment may be <strong>in</strong>dividuated, <strong>in</strong> effect the thrust of the cooperative prescription hasbeen to ensure mutual debt monitor<strong>in</strong>g. Funds are to be dispersed at 8% <strong>in</strong>terest, 7% of which is notably to bereta<strong>in</strong>ed by ‘<strong>in</strong>termediaries’, <strong>in</strong> this <strong>in</strong>stance SASA, and thus may represent a net transfer from government to the<strong>in</strong>dustry. 48 To some extent SACGA has nonetheless recognized the necessity of ensur<strong>in</strong>g a measure ofredistribution of proceeds with<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry to susta<strong>in</strong> SSG production. SSG <strong>in</strong>comes have recently beensubsidized by both a flat VAT and diesel rebate and disbursements from the Supplementary Payment Fund(SPF), 64% of which is effectively contributed by large-<strong>scale</strong> growers (deliver<strong>in</strong>g more than 5,000 tons cane) and36% by the mill<strong>in</strong>g companies. SACGA estimates that this has more than quadrupled growers’ net operat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>come, though with few hectares at their disposal, the effective returns rema<strong>in</strong> small, rang<strong>in</strong>g from R367 per hato R1,654 per ha. 49 While SACGA’s <strong>in</strong>terventions have not been unsubstantial, they have been <strong>in</strong>sufficient toarrest the rate of decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> SSG production. Indeed, by 2011 the number of registered growers has dropped to29,130 of which only 13,871 delivered cane, account<strong>in</strong>g for 8.59% of the national crop. 50To some extent, the failure of these new <strong>in</strong>stitutional mechanisms has been premised on a faultycharacterisation of the growth of SSG production <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong> as a product of a beneficent private-sector microcreditsystem designed to overcome the limits of a system of tribal tenure, or that SSGs could be characterizedas <strong>in</strong>dependent, albeit ‘develop<strong>in</strong>g’ farmers. Indeed, at one level the productive <strong>in</strong>terventions undertaken bymillers reflects the fiction of CF schemes as little more than a structured market relationship between discretebuyers and sellers of a particular commodity. As observed by Wilson (1986) “much like the wage contractbetween ‘free’ labourer and employer described and analyzed by Marx: the legal form [of the contract] conceals(and yet, on analysis, reveals) the system of social relations beneath it, its very abstractness provid<strong>in</strong>g a powerfulstrategy for capital accumulation and exploitation” 51 . Such a description certa<strong>in</strong>ly has strong resonances withearly mill strategies to expand SSG production, where supply relationships effectively appear as little more thana form of ‘’proletarianization without dispossession’’ and hence conversion of their land rights <strong>in</strong>to ‘’shamproperty’’.Little and Watts’ (1994) characterization of CF schemes as a form of ‘flexible’ accumulation takes suchan analytic one step from the abstract to the concrete <strong>in</strong> understand<strong>in</strong>g the qualitatively different forms thiseffective ‘wage-relationship’ took. As a ‘flexible’ mechanism to socially and technically <strong>in</strong>tegrate disparateproducers, the contract <strong>in</strong>deed afforded millers the capacity to adapt productive relations to qualitatively differentsocial circumstances of production. While the mill could count on the ‘capture’ of rural producers to undertake agreater share of production, <strong>in</strong> peri-urban areas it was the mill itself which undertook most of the productionprocess, which thus <strong>in</strong> some sense reflected little more than a more fragmented form of own-estate production.Glover and Kusterer’s (1990) description of CF as fundamentally concerned with allocat<strong>in</strong>g risk between47 Nothard, BW, Ortmann, GF & Meyer, E. 2005. “Attributes of <strong>Small</strong>-Scale Contractors That Influence Their Service Quality In <strong>KwaZulu</strong>-Nata”. Agrekon,44, 3. p. 41048 Dept. of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries. 2012. “Micro Agricultural F<strong>in</strong>ancial Institutions of South Africa”. Presentation to Parliament’s PortfolioCommittee on Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries. Accessed from Parliamentary Monitor<strong>in</strong>g Group (PMG) at http://www.pmg.org.za/report/20120807-department-agriculture-forestry-and-fisheries-brief<strong>in</strong>g49Armitage, RM,Hurley, KM and Gillitt, GG. 2009. “Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g Support Measures To <strong>Small</strong> Scale <strong>Growers</strong> And New Freehold <strong>Growers</strong>”. p.36350SASA. 2011/12. South African Sugar Industry Directory 2011/12. p.1351Wilson, J. 1986. “The Political Economy of Contract Farm<strong>in</strong>g”. Review of Radical Political Economics; 18.
processor/retailers and producers is similarly <strong>in</strong>structive. While millers’ prime motivation to engage <strong>in</strong> CFschemes was to facilitate access to SSGs’ otherwise commercially <strong>in</strong>alienable land, it was only with considerablesubsidy from both the <strong>in</strong>dustry and <strong>KwaZulu</strong> that millers were content to directly engage <strong>in</strong> production. Oncethese subsidies were effectively pulled, <strong>in</strong>terventions and supports to mitigate the risks of SSG production weresimilarly resc<strong>in</strong>ded while the numbers of SSGs expanded exponentially. Without subsidies to underp<strong>in</strong> SSGproduction, it would appear that the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> SSG numbers and the devolvement of logistical responsibilitiesto <strong>in</strong>dependent contractors formed part of a miller strategy to <strong>in</strong>sulate themselves from the costs and the risks ofSSG production whilst hedg<strong>in</strong>g total SSG production over a wider base.Despite the usefulness of analyses of CF as a concealed form of exploitation, a ‘flexible’ mechanism ofaccumulation or risk management however, there is little consensus on what the social impacts of CF are, orwhat they represent. For Wilson (1986), CF spurs differentiation, squeez<strong>in</strong>g producers and forc<strong>in</strong>g some towardsproletariats and others closer to agrarian equivalents of ‘branch managers’, but because mercantile controlrema<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> the hands of the processer, “the transformation of the farm <strong>in</strong>to a capitalist firm is blocked” 52 . ForGlover and Kusterer (1990) CF “is at least as likely to prevent social differentiation as to enhance it” 53 by<strong>in</strong>hibit<strong>in</strong>g differential capacity access to services, labour, markets and <strong>in</strong>puts under competitive circumstances.The variability of different CF schemes and different outcomes has led Oya (2008) to note that “it is reasonableto hypothesise that CF can hardly qualify as a dist<strong>in</strong>ct ‘road’ [to agrarian capitalism]” and that “there is noevidence that CF schemes substantially changed social relations <strong>in</strong> a clear direction rather than work<strong>in</strong>g onalready ongo<strong>in</strong>g processes of social change…though there is little doubt that <strong>in</strong> many places CF schemes havebeen catalytic for processes of social change and differentiation” 54 . Indeed, Oya to some extent agrees with Littleand Watts (1994) observation that CF (a) favours the participation of the middle- and upper-<strong>in</strong>come strata offarmers while (b) develop<strong>in</strong>g a small ‘top’ segment among smallholder outgrowers, who manage to prosperthanks to their much higher returns from CF. The question of how social relations among South Africa’s SSGproduction have changed under new productive relations and harsh agricultural conditions thus cannot bededuced apriori and requires exam<strong>in</strong>ation. The question is similarly pert<strong>in</strong>ent for SSGs <strong>in</strong> other Southern Africancountries, where landed populations be<strong>in</strong>g subsumed <strong>in</strong>to CF schemes to supply the same crop to branches ofthe very same companies that dom<strong>in</strong>ate the sector <strong>in</strong> South Africa.Report on fieldwork: SSGs <strong>in</strong> two rural wards of the Umfolozi supply areaMy fieldwork, the bulk of which was conducted between the latter half of 2010 up to early 2012, has beenconcentrated <strong>in</strong> the two adjacent wards of Madwaleni and Shikishela with<strong>in</strong> the Mpukunyoni tribal authority; twosugarcane grow<strong>in</strong>g ‘communities’ approximately 30+ km from <strong>Mtubatuba</strong> and the Umfolozi Sugar Mill (USM)which they supply. 55 In many ways the locus of my fieldwork must be placed with<strong>in</strong> a particular context beyondthe wider USM supply area and SSGs more broadly. In addition to be<strong>in</strong>g counted amongst the more ‘rural’ ra<strong>in</strong>fedSSG supply areas, USM has a particular history peculiar to the wider <strong>in</strong>dustry. Unlike the bulk of sugar millsowned by South Africa’s ‘big 3’ sugar companies (Tongaat-Huletts, C.G Smith/Illovo, and Tsb) for the bulk of itshistory USM has been cooperatively owned by its large-<strong>scale</strong> white commercial cane suppliers, most of whomare affiliated with<strong>in</strong> Umfolozi Sugar Planters Ltd (UCOSP). This picture is complicated by the mills’ purchase byIllovo <strong>in</strong> 1992, the subsequent sale of the mill (m<strong>in</strong>us ref<strong>in</strong>ery facilities) to Patrick Sokhela <strong>in</strong> 2005, its unwill<strong>in</strong>gre-purchase by Illovo and ultimate sale <strong>in</strong> 2009 to a consortium <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g UCOSP; UVS; Charles Senekal andNCP Alcohols. Currently a scheme is underway to facilitate SSG purchase of a 7% <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> USM as well.52Wilson, J. 1986. “The Political Economy of Contract Farm<strong>in</strong>g”. Review of Radical Political Economics; 18.53Glover, D and Kusterer, K. 1990. <strong>Small</strong> Farmers, Big Bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Contract Farm<strong>in</strong>g and Rural Development. London: Macmillan. p.14054Oya, C. 2008. “A contract-farm<strong>in</strong>g path to rural capitalism? Reflections and hypotheses on available evidence about contract farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Sub-SaharanAfrica”. Paper presented at the Journal of Agrarian Change Workshop ‘Agrarian Questions: L<strong>in</strong>eages and Prospects’. p. 3055While be<strong>in</strong>g hosted by a former SSG <strong>in</strong> Madwaleni, the fieldwork itself consisted firstly of an ‘extensive’ phase of adm<strong>in</strong>ister<strong>in</strong>g a survey of 70 registeredsugarcane-growers <strong>in</strong> dist<strong>in</strong>ct homesteads, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g 4 contractors, as well as a more ‘<strong>in</strong>tensive’ phase of conduct<strong>in</strong>g supplementary ‘life history’ <strong>in</strong>terviewswith a selected 20 sugarcane grower homesteads; attend<strong>in</strong>g 3 Development Committee Meet<strong>in</strong>gs, 2 Local Association meet<strong>in</strong>gs, 1 MCC meet<strong>in</strong>g, 1 Pestand Disease meet<strong>in</strong>g, and associated <strong>in</strong>terviews with mill and grower support staff.
The ex nihilio creation of a new <strong>in</strong>termediary class of black contractors, while superficially pursued to promoteentrepreneurial activity, occurred soon after the rationalisation of transport and the removal of ‘transport costs’from calculations of millers costs <strong>in</strong> the DoP; a correlation which is unlikely co<strong>in</strong>cidental. Nonetheless, theeventual devolvement of haulage and plough<strong>in</strong>g responsibilities to black contractors, followed by the deregulationof registration certa<strong>in</strong>ly corresponds with the <strong>in</strong>itial boom <strong>in</strong> numbers of SSGs. However, whileM<strong>in</strong>aar’s (1992) statistics <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>in</strong> 1989, 186 registered SSGs accounted for 53,682 tons of cane, millofficials estimate that 1,300 growers <strong>in</strong> 1992 accounted for 80,000 tons. In account<strong>in</strong>g for this vastdisproportional discrepancy, several po<strong>in</strong>ts are worth observ<strong>in</strong>g.Firstly, it is almost certa<strong>in</strong> that M<strong>in</strong>aar’s figures underestimated total SSG production; despite thesensitivity of the question, some growers admitted to submitt<strong>in</strong>g cane on a neighbour’s code before receiv<strong>in</strong>gtheir own prior to the removal of restrictions on registration. Secondly, black contractors were <strong>in</strong>strumental <strong>in</strong>encourag<strong>in</strong>g the uptake of sugarcane cultivation (and thereby expand<strong>in</strong>g their client base), particularly by way ofland-lease arrangements with small plot-holders with few resources. In such cases, an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> growernumbers may simply reflect registration for production already underway, or reflect the entrepreneurial activitiesof a smaller group of tractor owners. F<strong>in</strong>ally, for all other growers <strong>in</strong>terviewed, it is notable that <strong>in</strong>itial fund<strong>in</strong>g ofcane production (though <strong>in</strong> some cases preceded by cotton) was premised on sav<strong>in</strong>gs amassed from wages,salaries, and private pensions from migrant labour, typically by male homestead heads. Cane <strong>in</strong> this senserepresented a potential means by which to <strong>in</strong>vert the logic of agricultural production to the “worker-peasant”homestead, i.e. from a subsistence supplement to wage multiplier. Unsurpris<strong>in</strong>gly growers reported <strong>in</strong>itiallypursu<strong>in</strong>g conservative strategies <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g dear sav<strong>in</strong>gs; plant<strong>in</strong>g a small amount of land to cane and slowlyexpand<strong>in</strong>g by reserv<strong>in</strong>g portions of each cutt<strong>in</strong>g for new plant<strong>in</strong>gs. Very few growers claimed to have soughtassistance from FAF/UAF, preferr<strong>in</strong>g to use returns from cane to fund expansion rather than risk <strong>in</strong>debtednessand mill officials themselves estimate that credit was never extended to more than 25% of growers. Notably,those <strong>in</strong>terviewed who did ultimately undertake credit assistance only did so after already establish<strong>in</strong>g substantialplant<strong>in</strong>gs of >4 ha. Such conservative strategies thus may have also contributed to a ‘lag’ <strong>in</strong> production beh<strong>in</strong>dnumbers of growers actually registered.Despite the retraction of direct mill <strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong> production follow<strong>in</strong>g the devolvement ofresponsibilities to black contractors, however, mill section managers and field officers cont<strong>in</strong>ued to exert strong<strong>in</strong>fluence over logistics <strong>in</strong> transport and harvest<strong>in</strong>g, as well as oversight over applicants for FAF/UAF creditassistance. Paradoxically, however, the de-regulation of registration was accompanied by mill directives toresc<strong>in</strong>d such oversight responsibilities:“Though we were employed as extension officers, 80% of our time was spent chas<strong>in</strong>g contractors, hauliers and labourers, to make sure the cane is <strong>in</strong> themill with<strong>in</strong> three or four days. The tickets, that’s a full time job. And then the mill comes along says that’s not what you are employed to do.”“They took that teach<strong>in</strong>g away from me and told me to just go back and run my section. I had 3 guys underneath me. As the crop has gone down, theywere pulled out from me, one by one. Eventually I was runn<strong>in</strong>g the area on my own. As the estimate went down, they said it doesn’t pay us to keep theseguys on.’’For mill extension staff, the eventual restriction of such services, despite <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> the number of SSGs, wasbewilder<strong>in</strong>g. Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g acknowledgement that this was <strong>in</strong>fluenced by the mill’s own commercial pressures,the orig<strong>in</strong> of the retraction has largely been read as emanat<strong>in</strong>g from disgruntled growers seek<strong>in</strong>g the relaxation ofrestrictive oversight. That widespread default and fraud ultimately led to the closure of FAF/UAF’s services hasre<strong>in</strong>forced this viewpo<strong>in</strong>t:“FAF/UAF lent them money up front. The mill had the responsibility to manage that... We the mill were the agents of FAF. We used to go out and to <strong>in</strong>spectland as extension officers, make sure agriculturally you can grow sugarcane, that the <strong>in</strong>frastructure is there for the drop off …and Umfolozi was one of thebest <strong>in</strong> ensur<strong>in</strong>g the money was paid back, because of the discipl<strong>in</strong>e of the office. But they compla<strong>in</strong>ed we were too authoritarian <strong>in</strong> decid<strong>in</strong>g who couldhave a loan, ask<strong>in</strong>g ‘what right do you have to tell me if I can have a loan; you don’t live out here or know me?’ They then told FAF they wanted it changed.And they did…. So I backed off and told management, ‘how can I be part and parcel of the fun and games out there?’. Eventually, UAF got to the po<strong>in</strong>t
where they had lent out R100,000,000… The chairperson and secretary were even duck<strong>in</strong>g and div<strong>in</strong>g. So what happened? The hand that was feed<strong>in</strong>gthem, they cut it off. The f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>stitution help<strong>in</strong>g them; they screwed it up.’’For SSGs by contrast, narratives of change are significantly different. For those who have lived throughsuch different <strong>in</strong>stitutional relations of production, the reduction <strong>in</strong> support has been <strong>in</strong>terpreted as a corollary ofdemocracy and the decl<strong>in</strong>e of the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> state. As a local grower chairperson and farmer from the orig<strong>in</strong>al‘Group of 7’ elaborated at a Local Association meet<strong>in</strong>g:“When myself, [MPB] and [Mr S] first got <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess of farm<strong>in</strong>g sugar it was under the apartheid government. I want to request, once aga<strong>in</strong>,that we go back to where we started under the apartheid regime... It was <strong>in</strong> 1979 that the first sugarcane farm<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess was established <strong>in</strong> Mpukunyoni.Just after we started, <strong>in</strong> 1980, there was a major drought which destroyed almost everyth<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g many cattle….Some compensation funds weremade available. We benefitted. I was given R15, 000 cash from the two hectares destroyed by the drought. This was not a loan. All one had to do was togo to the office, sign some documents and the money would be put <strong>in</strong>to your bank account. I took the cash and used it for cultivation, buy<strong>in</strong>g gra<strong>in</strong>. Thiswas 1981, then it was ’82, ’83 and <strong>in</strong> ’84 drought came and, once aga<strong>in</strong>, destroyed all our crops. For this, there was, once aga<strong>in</strong> a compensation fund thatwas made available. By? The <strong>KwaZulu</strong> government. This time around I was given R7,800. I took the amount, fixed my sugarcane and used the rest for myfamily. Now that was a government which, I say, was sympathetic to the aspirations and plight of farmers...Then came 1994. The election came and wewere made to believe the country was back to its rightful owners. We were told that the days of hunger and suffer<strong>in</strong>g for the black people were over. Theyears went by, and it seems as if they have forgotten about us as sugarcane farmers… This contrasts sharply with 1981 and 1984. M<strong>in</strong>isters of Agriculturehave come and gone and not a s<strong>in</strong>gle one of them has been prepared to listen to the views and concerns of sugarcane farmers <strong>in</strong> this area.”When read together, these narratives complicate the conventional description of decl<strong>in</strong>e focused solely on theimmutable factor of drought. Of particular importance have been the shifts <strong>in</strong> the basis of SSGs’ relationship tothe mill; from a system def<strong>in</strong>ed by direct miller control and oversight over production and logistics with momentsof direct state assistance, to the gradual devolvement of productive and logistical responsibility to a much widernumber of SSGs and contractors. As argued earlier, this was ultimately precipitated by shifts <strong>in</strong> the wider politicaleconomy of the sugar <strong>in</strong>dustry, particularly <strong>in</strong> its regulatory structure and the removal of the effective subsidiesenjoyed by millers to pursue SSG production. A pernicious aspect of these changes, however, has been theirrelative obscurity, and growers and extension staff who have persisted through them have largely been left toextrapolate explanations derived from <strong>in</strong>terface at the level of direct production.However, for the majority of farmers I <strong>in</strong>terviewed, and for whom production only began <strong>in</strong> the 1990s theexperience of decl<strong>in</strong>e has certa<strong>in</strong>ly been def<strong>in</strong>ed by such immediate pressures on production. Commonly citedfactors <strong>in</strong>clude the considerable drought; high <strong>in</strong>put, labour, and transport costs; and transport delays; theconfluence of which has certa<strong>in</strong>ly been severe. Indeed of the 45 growers who gave me access to their <strong>in</strong>dividualproduction data held by SACGA, mean sucrose content of cane was found to be 7.39% aga<strong>in</strong>st and <strong>in</strong>dustryaverage of around 14% and with only 4 growers receiv<strong>in</strong>g greater than 8%. It must be observed, however thatthis conflicts with USM’s own quality records, which show the top 10 highest SSG sucrose percentages to beabove 16%, and the lowest 10 to be around 11%. A typical account from NS, a widow from a polygamousmarriage, exemplifies the experience of decl<strong>in</strong>e:“Now, however, [NS] only has 23 l<strong>in</strong>es on about 1/8 ha (down from 3 ha of cane), and <strong>in</strong> 2011 only cut ½ ha. She says that the ma<strong>in</strong> reason for her drop <strong>in</strong>production was drought: as she received less money, she was unable to purchase enough fertilizer or hire enough labour for weed<strong>in</strong>g. She doesn’t know ifth<strong>in</strong>gs got more expensive because she would just buy th<strong>in</strong>gs as they were needed, but she suspects that the tractors got more expensive, perhaps due to<strong>in</strong>creased diesel costs. However, because she doesn’t know how to use the cow for plough<strong>in</strong>g, she is dependent on the tractors, and because of decreasedreturns she couldn’t afford to replant. Previously, she would use money from her Child Support Grant and Disability Grant to pay the tractor, while us<strong>in</strong>g themoney from cane to cover other farm<strong>in</strong>g and consumption costs, but now she needs to use the grant for consumption. She said she would not take a loanfor fear of debt, but still needs money to purchase fertilizer and to pay for labour, which she cannot get for free, even from her children. It is the samesituation with her husband’s other wives. Nonetheless, she hopes to slowly expand by us<strong>in</strong>g her current crop as seed cane.”While such pressures might be pervasive, their impacts are uneven. In depth life-history <strong>in</strong>terviewsconducted with 22 growers and grouped with an adaptation of the typology by Scoones et al (2011) 60 reveal avariety of productive trajectories amongst differentially resourced growers, both <strong>in</strong> terms of relative levels ofproduction and the impact of cane on dynamics of homestead social reproduction. They go some way to help60See Appendix for a tabled schematic
illum<strong>in</strong>ate the dynamics of social differentiation follow<strong>in</strong>g the retraction of miller <strong>in</strong>terventions and hence furtherembedd<strong>in</strong>g productive tensions with<strong>in</strong> the prevail<strong>in</strong>g local social structure.As was observed earlier, the widespread uptake of cane <strong>in</strong> the 1990s was premised either on the<strong>in</strong>vestment of sav<strong>in</strong>gs garnered <strong>in</strong> wage labour or via lease-hold arrangements with neighbours, and as such itscontribution to homestead reproduction dynamics has largely been def<strong>in</strong>ed by its value as a strategy ofdiversification, either for survival or accumulation. The relative value of cane has thus been <strong>in</strong>timately bound withnon-cane sources of <strong>in</strong>come, and perhaps unsurpris<strong>in</strong>gly has played a def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of grower trajectories underharsh productive circumstances. Notably, all 7 cases where growers are dropp<strong>in</strong>g or have dropped out ofproduction are represented by female growers, 5 of which cite the <strong>in</strong>itiation of cane as premised on thecontribution of wages or sav<strong>in</strong>gs by a male partner, with production falter<strong>in</strong>g after their death or <strong>in</strong>capacitation. Inthe other 2 <strong>in</strong>stances, production began by via a land-lease arrangement <strong>in</strong> the absence of a male partner, andone other homestead was reliant on the mill services to establish the crop. In these cases, subsequent ratoonswere utilized as a slight annual subsidy to consumption, with little effective capacity for re<strong>in</strong>vestment. For JM bycontrast, ‘stepp<strong>in</strong>g’ rather than dropp<strong>in</strong>g down has been premised on susta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>put purchases from heremployed son, follow<strong>in</strong>g her husband’s decision to resc<strong>in</strong>d f<strong>in</strong>ancial contributions.Where the homestead <strong>in</strong>cludes employed members, however, <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> cane is not <strong>in</strong>evitable. Inthe 3 ‘stepp<strong>in</strong>g out’ cases growers <strong>in</strong>dicated that the decl<strong>in</strong>e of cane has rendered other forms of landed<strong>in</strong>vestment more appeal<strong>in</strong>g. All of these cases have considerable cattle endowments, and the <strong>in</strong>duna explicitlynoted that grow<strong>in</strong>g his herd will supplant cane as his chief focus. In the other 2 cases permanently employedhomestead members with substantial <strong>in</strong>comes provide the bulk of homestead earn<strong>in</strong>gs, and both rema<strong>in</strong>sceptical about re-<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> cane, with 1 consider<strong>in</strong>g grow<strong>in</strong>g gumtrees after a failed attempt at broilerproduction. For 2 of the women who have ‘dropped out’ of cane altogether, the presence of employedhomestead members presents the possibility of re-start<strong>in</strong>g production if they could be conv<strong>in</strong>ced to commit theirearn<strong>in</strong>gs to <strong>in</strong>put purchases. Both nonetheless <strong>in</strong>dicate that this would only occur if conditions improve, i.e.should cane become an attractive <strong>in</strong>vestment opportunity once aga<strong>in</strong>.In addition to employment, social grants have played a def<strong>in</strong>itive role both on <strong>in</strong>dividual growertrajectories and on the social character of SSG production. Most basically, social grants have been <strong>in</strong>strumental<strong>in</strong> form<strong>in</strong>g a consumptive basel<strong>in</strong>e for homesteads qualify<strong>in</strong>g for old-age grants (R1,200), though importantlysupplemented by child support grants (CSG) (R280) as well as the less pervasive disability (R1200) and fostercare grants (R770). Indeed, with a median age of 61.5 and 72.7% (n=48) of SSGs self-declared heads ofrelatively large homesteads with low levels of absenteeism, the old age grant <strong>in</strong> particular appears to similarlyhave re<strong>in</strong>forced Zulu customs of vest<strong>in</strong>g authority over land <strong>in</strong> senior members. 61 Particularly for those who hadpreviously depended chiefly on <strong>in</strong>come from cane, social grants have enabled some growers to re-<strong>in</strong>vest caneproceeds enabl<strong>in</strong>g consistent food and other basic consumptive purchases from major retailers <strong>in</strong> <strong>Mtubatuba</strong>.For VM, this has entailed ‘stepp<strong>in</strong>g down’ production to 4 ha from a full 15ha ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed with FAF. For AZstay<strong>in</strong>g exclusively with<strong>in</strong> the consumptive bounds of grants and reed-mat sales and allegedly rely<strong>in</strong>g exclusivelyon unpaid family labour has enabled her to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> full production on 6ha.Similarly, social grants have also helped alleviate the impact of ‘dropp<strong>in</strong>g out’ and ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>edaspirations for cont<strong>in</strong>ued cane production. For growers such as NS and ZM social grants have <strong>in</strong>spired a strategyof ‘creep<strong>in</strong>g back’ <strong>in</strong>to production, with marg<strong>in</strong>al re<strong>in</strong>vestment from cane submissions. The essential strategyentails utiliz<strong>in</strong>g a portion of annual cutt<strong>in</strong>gs as seedcane and us<strong>in</strong>g proceeds from submitted balance of theharvest to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>put purchases, whilst rely<strong>in</strong>g exclusively on social grants to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> consumption. Forhomesteads with neither access to either permanent jobs or pensions, however, the situation is more dire, and itis notable that the 3 homesteads encountered which rely pr<strong>in</strong>cipally reliant on wages from local casualagricultural labour <strong>in</strong>clude young unmarried mothers without access to either old-age or disability grants. Whileall are attempt<strong>in</strong>g to restart production, 1 has been compelled to plant without fertilizer, with the 2 others enter<strong>in</strong>g61The median homestead size is 10, and median members present all or most nights is 8.
<strong>in</strong>to cane-establishment/land-lease arrangements to do so. Without susta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>vestment and amidst low ra<strong>in</strong>fallhowever, such ratoons are unlikely to yield more than marg<strong>in</strong>al proceeds.Ironically however, SSGs often blame social grants as the orig<strong>in</strong>s of their difficulties <strong>in</strong> the sourc<strong>in</strong>g,management and expense of labour. Though often form<strong>in</strong>g the consumptive base of their own homesteads,SSGs frequently compla<strong>in</strong> of labour both with<strong>in</strong> the homestead and of those hired <strong>in</strong> from ‘neighbours’ as be<strong>in</strong>g‘lazy’: demand<strong>in</strong>g of seem<strong>in</strong>gly unreasonable wages or simply unwill<strong>in</strong>g to work. Despite the pejorative nature ofsuch characterizations, however, <strong>in</strong> stabiliz<strong>in</strong>g consumption it is likely that access to social grants has bothmitigated the desperation of poor homesteads and contributed to the monetization of social relations ofreciprocity more broadly. Besides the three women referred to above, <strong>in</strong> all other cases wages from local casualagricultural labour represented a supplement to personal consumption, particularly for young men and schoolgo<strong>in</strong>gchildren member to homesteads with access to significant employment and/or old-age and disabilitygrants.Furthermore, despite the improved relative barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g position of casual labour, as the absolute value ofwages rema<strong>in</strong> too small to form a significant contribution to ceremonial funds such as lobola or susta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>dependent conjugal households, sourc<strong>in</strong>g labour for cane production rema<strong>in</strong>s difficult for SSGs. This isparticularly true of the most <strong>in</strong>tensive task of harvest<strong>in</strong>g, which must be done timeously to ensure prompttransportation. The relative dearth of ‘desperate’ labour is further exacerbated by difficulties <strong>in</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>ghomestead labour, with youth typically <strong>in</strong> school or seek<strong>in</strong>g other opportunities. Frequently, mobiliz<strong>in</strong>ghomestead labour requires a mix of familial discipl<strong>in</strong>e and enticement with equal or lower-than-average wages,and <strong>in</strong>deed hir<strong>in</strong>g labour <strong>in</strong> many cases is a signal more of homestead fracture than accumulation. The high costof labour thus compels many SSGs to either <strong>in</strong>tensify self-exploitation either directly or via reciprocal, usuallypaid, labour arrangements with neighbour<strong>in</strong>g homesteads, or to attempt <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> labour-sav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>puts suchas herbicides and top-dress<strong>in</strong>g.Other than labour, the services provided by a limited number of local black contractors and outsidehauliers are similarly cited as a chief concern. More than 40% of growers cited field to load<strong>in</strong>g zone (LZ)transport delays from black contractors, and 60% of growers cited LZ to mill delays of more than five days. Thatsuch delays contribute to the deterioration of sucrose content and were reportedly almost universal almostcerta<strong>in</strong>ly has contributed to the uniformly low sucrose values of differentially resourced growers of vary<strong>in</strong>g skilland capacity. Moreover, of the 28 growers who both allowed me to access their production codes for analysisand made available their transport receipts, transport costs alone accounted for an average of 33% of revenue.As seen from the testimony of NS above, SSGs tend to be publically sympathetic to the constra<strong>in</strong>ts of fewavailable contractors and of their own capacities to coord<strong>in</strong>ate timeous harvest, preferr<strong>in</strong>g to apportion blame tosocially distant private haulier services. Nonetheless, the high costs of plough<strong>in</strong>g and transport, coupled with thenegative quality impacts of poor services, exposes the ultimately antagonistic <strong>in</strong>terests of contractors andexacerbates disgruntlement over their claim to proceeds. As observed by one grower:“Contractors and hauliers are also expensive, and often provide substandard services. For <strong>in</strong>stance, when they crack the soil they plough very shallowrows, which reduces the number of ratoons you can get from one plant<strong>in</strong>g, say 8 <strong>in</strong>stead of 15. Also, they do not pack the rows tightly enough, say do<strong>in</strong>g 60l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong>stead of 100 per ha, which means you plant less cane and get more weeds. A further problem is that growers must pay for transport <strong>in</strong> tonnage ofcane, but only get paid for sucrose content. So if the grower’s sucrose value drops from drought or transport delays, the grower gets paid less, but thecontractor gets paid the same amount, even if they are late.’’Undoubtedly, surviv<strong>in</strong>g grower-contractors represent the big ‘w<strong>in</strong>ners’ who have emerged from thespace afforded by the retraction of mill services and oversight <strong>in</strong> transport, and their prom<strong>in</strong>ence is probably themost strik<strong>in</strong>g feature of shift<strong>in</strong>g SSG relations. Each of the 5 grower-contractors <strong>in</strong>terviewed are substantial landowners at (6ha, 12ha, 12ha, 11ha and 25 ha) with no other employed homestead members. Not only have theyma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed full production and rely chiefly on casual labour, but are cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g to expand both <strong>in</strong> terms of capitaland land purchases, despite the supposed limitation on commercial transfer posed by customary tenure.Although contract<strong>in</strong>g reportedly generates far more <strong>in</strong>come than sugarcane (R30-80,000 vs R10-40,000),
SSG/contractors have noted that cross-subsidization of the contract<strong>in</strong>g and sugarcane enterprises has been thekey determ<strong>in</strong>ant of their success with recurrent sugarcane costs provided largely by contract<strong>in</strong>g returns andannual tractor ma<strong>in</strong>tenance bulk sugarcane payments, though it must be noted that tractor breakdowns occurfrequently. One longstand<strong>in</strong>g contractor suggested that though only about 5 contractors rema<strong>in</strong> of a peak of 12,that many of those who dropped out did not have sugarcane fields of their own, or bulk sugarcane proceeds tofund full tractor servic<strong>in</strong>g at the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of each year. Such services, however, categorically represent a claimon SSG proceeds and place contractors <strong>in</strong> opposition to their clients, a reality accentuated by muted competitionamongst a small number of contractors servic<strong>in</strong>g a wide area. One mill official observed for <strong>in</strong>stance, that there isa lower price threshold which none go below, despite denial of such practices by contractors themselves. The fullextent of such collusion is unknown, but with high costs of ma<strong>in</strong>tenance and with little competition, there iscerta<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong>centive and opportunity for contractors to do so. Two of these homesteads are directly related, withone contractor (11ha) be<strong>in</strong>g the grandson of another (12ha).ConclusionAs has been argued, the growth of SSG production <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong> has been mischaracterized as a product of theextension of a beneficent micro-credit system to <strong>in</strong>dependent albeit ‘develop<strong>in</strong>g’ farmers <strong>in</strong>hibited by a system oftribal tenure. While FAF operated as an important <strong>in</strong>stitutional mechanism, it was embedded with<strong>in</strong> a materialand political relationship with the <strong>KwaZulu</strong> state, and with<strong>in</strong> a particular regulatory structure; a structure which notonly differentially awarded millers for SSG production but also allowed them to claim an <strong>in</strong>creased proportion oftotal <strong>in</strong>dustry proceeds. This was further exacerbated by a tendency towards corporate consolidation of mill<strong>in</strong>gcapital and an imperative to augment throughput by ‘chas<strong>in</strong>g cane’ wherever possible.The net effect was that the appearance of SSGs as ‘<strong>in</strong>dependent farmers’ facilitated by <strong>in</strong>novative creditfacilities masked the actual nature of their relationship with millers. In more rural areas, this relationship moreclosely resembled that between employer and employee, with extension staff act<strong>in</strong>g largely as managers,lend<strong>in</strong>g close oversight over production and transport operations of SSGs responsible for the procurement oflabour. In peri-urban areas, the facade of <strong>in</strong>dependence was underm<strong>in</strong>ed by the reality that little of the productionprocess was actually carried out by SSGs themselves; a relationship that ultimately manifested more as onebetween lessor-lessee than supplier-purchaser. In both <strong>in</strong>stances, Wilson’s (1986) characterization of CF as aform of “proletarianization without dispossession’’ seems appropriate. This relationship was further obscured,however, by the <strong>in</strong>troduction of small-<strong>scale</strong> contractors, themselves ultimately reliant on compet<strong>in</strong>g for, orcollud<strong>in</strong>g to augment claims upon the product of disparate producersThe lift<strong>in</strong>g of restrictions on registration <strong>in</strong> 1990s <strong>in</strong> tandem with the removal of the <strong>in</strong>tensive supportsupon which SSG production had been predicated thus positioned the second wave of SSG growth as structurallyunsound. In many ways this rapid growth <strong>in</strong> SSG production resembled a ‘bubble’ not altogether different fromthose <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets, summarily ‘popped’ by the harsh circumstances of drought. Glover and Kusterer’s(1990) characterization of CF as mechanism of risk management helps position miller’s adaption to thesechanges; from one where SSG production and gradual expansion was assured via <strong>in</strong>tensive management and<strong>in</strong>tervention , to one where risks to throughput would effectively be hedged amongst a much larger population ofgrowers without direct support.However, as black South Africans had already been ‘proletarianized’ under colonial and the apartheidrule, this begs the question of what further social impacts SSG production has had. Evidence from my fieldworksuggests a certa<strong>in</strong> consonance with Oya (2008) that social difference has been def<strong>in</strong>ed more by ongo<strong>in</strong>gprocesses of social differentiation than by the <strong>in</strong>troduction of sugarcane; particularly historical dispossession andstructural unemployment. This is somewhat manifest <strong>in</strong> the close correlations between distributions of assetwealth and grades of employment, as well as heavily unequal land distributions (<strong>in</strong>fluenced but not determ<strong>in</strong>edby sugarcane cultivation). Nonetheless, <strong>in</strong>terviews with SSGs farm<strong>in</strong>g from the 1990s show that where non-cane<strong>in</strong>come sources are available, sugarcane has represented an important form of <strong>in</strong>come diversification whether forsurvival or accumulation, but represents an ever-more risky <strong>in</strong>vestment under drought conditions. Moreover, the
prom<strong>in</strong>ence of social grants <strong>in</strong> support<strong>in</strong>g the consumptive base of most homesteads centred on senior old-agegrant recipients appears to have on the one hand raised the ‘desperation threshold’ of casual agricultural labour,but also provided a reliable basis for some homesteads to ‘hang-<strong>in</strong>’; ‘step-down’; or ‘creep back’ <strong>in</strong>to production.Indeed, of all female SSGs who have/are dropped/dropp<strong>in</strong>g out of production, only those without substantiveaccess to pensions or disability grants have been compelled to sell their labour locally as a matter of survival. Forthe rest, drops <strong>in</strong> production have been premised not only on drought, but either the loss of a non-cane <strong>in</strong>comesource, often through the death or <strong>in</strong>capacitation of a male partner, or scepticism of about <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g such <strong>in</strong>comewhere it is available.The most obvious exceptions to these trends have been contractors, all of whom have either ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>edfull cane production or are expand<strong>in</strong>g, and perhaps the only representatives of a clear <strong>in</strong>stance of socialdifferentiation attributable primarily to the <strong>in</strong>troduction of sugarcane. In all cases, the ma<strong>in</strong>tenance of productionhas been premised on the <strong>in</strong>terdependence of sugarcane and contract<strong>in</strong>g operations, but with the bulk of <strong>in</strong>comecom<strong>in</strong>g from the contract<strong>in</strong>g side. In one sense, contractors represent a certa<strong>in</strong> conformation of Little and Watts(1994) broad observation that CF tends to favour the development of a ‘top’ strata of farmers, with most hav<strong>in</strong>gaccess to large swathes of land, and some of whom had been engaged <strong>in</strong> the production of other cash-cropssuch as cotton before switch<strong>in</strong>g to sugarcane. However, <strong>in</strong> at least one case (UM), expansion has proceededfrom a relatively low base (4ha), <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that it is the <strong>in</strong>come afforded by contract<strong>in</strong>g which has provided theresources for accumulation. Nonetheless, the situat<strong>in</strong>g of contractors’ <strong>in</strong>terests as <strong>in</strong>imical to but dependant onSSGs production positions contract<strong>in</strong>g as a limited space for ‘pockets’ of accumulation; a space which wasultimately devolved by millers’ authority.Although Oya is correct to rema<strong>in</strong> sceptical about categorically designat<strong>in</strong>g CF as a particular ‘path’ ofaccumulation, <strong>in</strong> the case of sugar <strong>in</strong> South Africa, its historical basis <strong>in</strong> subsidized miller <strong>in</strong>itiatives and currenttrend towards consolidat<strong>in</strong>g a class of <strong>in</strong>termediary contractors, <strong>in</strong>dicate it can be characterized as accumulationfrom ‘above’. From such an analysis, one potential response is to recognize sugarcane-CF relations asessentially <strong>in</strong>dustrial <strong>in</strong> character i.e as employee/employer relationship. The question of SSG ‘development’ orwelfare thus cannot be reduced solely to questions of productive efficiency or <strong>in</strong>stitutional<strong>in</strong>novation/improvement, and must reta<strong>in</strong> a close focus on distributions of relative surplus and externalizations ofcost between millers, growers (both LSGs and SSGs <strong>in</strong> South Africa) as well as the position of <strong>in</strong>termediariessuch as contractors. For example, with millers benefit<strong>in</strong>g from both externaliz<strong>in</strong>g the cost/logistical responsibilityover transport and sublimat<strong>in</strong>g productive tensions with<strong>in</strong> SSG communities, and with surviv<strong>in</strong>g contractorsbenefit<strong>in</strong>g from non-competitive claims on SSG surplus, there appears little evidence to suggest that SSGsgenerally have benefited from the devolvement of contractual services. Nonetheless, while the devolvement ofnon-core functions to contractors appears to offer little more than ‘pockets’ of accumulation for relatively few(typically but not exclusively local elites) it rema<strong>in</strong>s an important ‘space’ for those who <strong>in</strong>habit it. The otherresponse thus is to devolve more such opportunities to SSGs and open more spaces for accumulation outside ofprimary production, for example <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>itial process<strong>in</strong>g or <strong>in</strong> small-<strong>scale</strong> mill<strong>in</strong>g.
Works CitedArmitage, RM,Hurley, KM and Gillitt, GG. 2009. ‘’Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g Support Measures To <strong>Small</strong> Scale <strong>Growers</strong> AndNew Freehold <strong>Growers</strong> In The South African Sugar Industry’’. Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs of the South African SugarTechnologists Association, 82.Bates, R. and Sokhela, P. 2003. ‘’The Development of <strong>Small</strong>-Scale Sugar Cane <strong>Growers</strong>: A Success Story?’’ <strong>in</strong>Nieuwoudt, L and Groenewald, J (eds) The Challenge of Change: Agriculture, Land and the South AfricanEconomy. University of <strong>Natal</strong> Press: Pietermaritzburg.Board of Trade and Industries. 1976. Investigation <strong>in</strong>to the division of proceeds of the Sugar Industry <strong>in</strong> SouthAfrica. Republic of South Africa.Cobbett, M. 1984. ‘’<strong>Sugarcane</strong> farm<strong>in</strong>g n <strong>KwaZulu</strong>: two communities <strong>in</strong>vestigated’’. Issue 58 of CarnegieConference paper. SALDRU, School of Economics, University of Cape Town.Dept. of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries. 2012. “Micro Agricultural F<strong>in</strong>ancial Institutions of SouthAfrica”. Presentation to Parliament’s Portfolio Committee on Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries.Accessed from Parliamentary Monitor<strong>in</strong>g Group (PMG) at http://www.pmg.org.za/report/20120807-department-agriculture-forestry-and-fisheries-brief<strong>in</strong>gDepartment of Trade and Industry. 2003? A discussion document on the review of the Sugar Act. Pretoria?Eweg, M. 2009. Def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Partnerships <strong>in</strong> South African Agriculture. South African <strong>Sugarcane</strong> Research Institute.Eaton, C and Shepard, A. 2001. “Contract Farm<strong>in</strong>g: Partnerships for growth, A Guide”. FAO Agricultural ServicesBullet<strong>in</strong> 145.Glover, D and Kusterer, K. 1990. <strong>Small</strong> Farmers, Big Bus<strong>in</strong>ess: Contract Farm<strong>in</strong>g and Rural Development.London: Macmillan.Hall, R. 2011. “The next Great Trek? South African commercial farmers move north” Paper presented for theInternational Conference on Global Land Grabb<strong>in</strong>g at the Institute of Development Studies (IDS).Little P. and M. Watts. 1994. Liv<strong>in</strong>g Under Contract: Contract Farm<strong>in</strong>g and Agrarian Transformation <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa. Madison: University of Wiscons<strong>in</strong> Press.M<strong>in</strong>aar, A de V. 1992. UShukela: a history of the growth and development of the sugar <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> Zululand:1905to the present. HSRC Press.Munro, W.A. 1996. “Contract farm<strong>in</strong>g, community development and the politics of production among smallgrowers<strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong>-<strong>Natal</strong>”. Sem<strong>in</strong>ar paper 392, presented at University of the Witwatersrand, Institute forAdvanced Social Research.Nedbank. 1974. Sugar and the South African Sugar <strong>in</strong>dustry: A Critical Assessment. Nedsual Economic Unit:Johannesburg.Nothard, BW, Ortmann, GF & Meyer, E. 2005. Attributes of <strong>Small</strong>-Scale Contractors That Influence Their ServiceQuality In <strong>KwaZulu</strong>-<strong>Natal</strong>. Agrekon, 44, 3.
Oya, C. 2008. “A contract-farm<strong>in</strong>g path to rural capitalism? Reflections and hypotheses on available evidenceabout contract farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa” Paper presented at the Journal of Agrarian Change Workshop‘Agrarian Questions: L<strong>in</strong>eages and Prospects’.Rahman, Shafiur. 1997. Aspects of Deregulation <strong>in</strong> the South African Sugar Industry: Implications for <strong>Small</strong>Holders. Unpublished paper.Richardson, B. 2010. “Big Sugar <strong>in</strong> southern Africa: rural development and the perverted potential ofsugar/ethanol exports”. Journal of Peasant Studies. 37, 4.Rorich, A. J. V. 1982. Report of the Committee of Inquiry <strong>in</strong>to the Sugar Industry, Republic of South Africa.SASA. 2011/12. South African Sugar Industry Directory 2011/12. Durban.SASYB. 1971/2. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1971/2. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal.SASYB. 1972/3. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1972/3. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal.SASYB. 1974/5. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1974/5. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal.SASYB. 1975/6. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1975/6. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal.SASYB. 1978/9. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1978/9. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal.SASYB. 1981/2. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1981/2. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal.SASYB. 1984/5. The South African Sugar yearbook, 1984/5. Durban: The South African Sugar Journal.Scoones, I; Marongwe, N; Mavedzenge, B; Mahenehene, J; Murimbarimba, F; and Sukume, C. 2011.Zimbabwe’s Land Reform: Myths and Realities. Jacana Media: Auckland Park.Van Biljon, F.J. 1970. Commission of <strong>in</strong>quiry Into the Sugar Industry. Republic of South AfricaVaughan, A. 1991. Cane, Class and Credit: Report on Fieldwork – Glendale Mill Area. Institute for Social andEconomic Research: University of Durban-Westville.Vaughn, Anne. 1992a. “Commercial Cane Production <strong>in</strong> <strong>KwaZulu</strong>: A Modernis<strong>in</strong>g Initiative?’’. Paper presented atthe Seventh Biennial Conference of the Economic History Society of Southern Africa, University of <strong>Natal</strong>.Vaughan, Anne. 1992b. “Options for rural restructur<strong>in</strong>g’’ <strong>in</strong> Robert Schire (ed) Wealth or Poverty? CriticalChoices for South Africa. Oxford University Press Southern Africa: Cape Town.Vaughan, A. and McIntosh. 1993. “State and Capital <strong>in</strong> the Regeneration of a South African Peasantry’’Canadian Journal of African Studies, 27, 3.Wilson. 1986. “The Political Economy of Contract Farm<strong>in</strong>g”. Review of Radical Political Economics; 18.
World Bank. 2007. “Overview” World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development, World Bank,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C.
APPENDIX: SSG TrajectoriesSSGWard AsstNon-Tot. LandRank Land Use AUC GrantIncomeMrMPB Mad. 4 20haMr ZSnr. Shiki. 4Mr ZJnr.Shiki. 4Mr TN Mad. 4MrUM12ha11ha24.5ha20ha8 ha 8 ha7 ha 7 ha14.5haMad. 3 6 ha4.25haMr M Mad. 412haMs AZ Mad. 36.5ha12ha6.5ha? 2 Perm Yes 014ha4 ha12haMs IM Mad. 4 8 ha 1 ha 1 haContractor1 TempLivestock SaleTrac Cows Labour Relationto HheadYes 12Ma<strong>in</strong>lycasuallabourCasuallabouronlyContraMa<strong>in</strong>lyctor1 Temp Yes 12 casuallabourContractor1 Perm;2Temp;TractorRentalContractorTuckshop4 CasAg6 ha Sell<strong>in</strong>gmeilies3 Perm;tractorrentalYes 19Yes 4Ma<strong>in</strong>lycasuallabourMixedlabourSSG SSGAge SexSSGMarryHH CaneSize Year<strong>Natal</strong> home/Arriv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>Madwaleni & ShikishelaSelf 90 M Yes;Arrive <strong>in</strong> Mad. w/ belong<strong>in</strong>gs &dead 13 1979 100+ cattle, allocated largeland. Father is pastor;Forced removal from St. Lucia.cont<strong>in</strong>ue to use & sell cattle.Self 57 M Yes;alive26 1982Mother 26 M No 10 1997Father 31 M No 7 1992Self 64 M Yes;aliveYes 0 Father 50 M Yes;aliveNo 0Yes 9HomelabouronlySelf 71 FMa<strong>in</strong>lycasual Husband 44 Flabour22 199717 1998Born <strong>in</strong> Shiki. Father ispoliceman, gives his 3ha away.Born <strong>in</strong> Shiki. Father's land 4ha, 1 ha crops. Father works atSpoornet. 1997 <strong>in</strong>vests sav<strong>in</strong>gs<strong>in</strong> cane; buys tractor <strong>in</strong> 2001,beg<strong>in</strong>s plough<strong>in</strong>g servicesBorn <strong>in</strong> Mad. 25 ha. Father exlabourtenant <strong>in</strong> Vryheid,evicted 1971. Land for food, &cattle but also cabbage &cotton for sale. Cottonprocessor closes 1991,switches to caneForced removal from St Lucia.Arrive <strong>in</strong> Mad. on 1 ha. Father& uncles=LSG cane labour.1974 receives 2 ha from MPBuyazi, & 2ha from neighborFather was ex-labour tenant,forced to leave all belong<strong>in</strong>gsfor NCP job; moves to Mad.Uses land for cropp<strong>in</strong>g &cattle. 1991 father retiresBorn <strong>in</strong> Swaziland-> moves toCA elsewhere. At 17 leaves forfarmwork for 3 years, marriesYes;dead 10 1990 Nkandla farmworker. Togetherflee Nkandla witches, arrive <strong>in</strong>Mad. Husband dies 2 yearslater.Yes;alive10 1992Ex-Vryheid labourtenants.Family moves to Mad.IM marries neighbor bus driverwith 8 ha; IM & sisters, mother<strong>in</strong>-lawgrow food.Basic Economy/Start<strong>in</strong>g CaneBeg<strong>in</strong>s cane 1979 with 'group of 7'.Expands to 20 ha. Cane pays forfood; sons' education & lobola; &funds general store (burns down)Works on LSCF until allocated 5ha<strong>in</strong> 1982, starts cane on 4ha. 1989buys tractor from LSCF; 1995began contract<strong>in</strong>g. Expands landto 12 ha via (purchase, clear<strong>in</strong>g &govt).In 2003 father buys 7ha fromneighbors for cane, other 4ha forgraz<strong>in</strong>g but dies 2005 from'sickness'. Mother decides to buytrailer for cane transport services.Hires labour & works onneighbors land to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> labourrelations.Bought 1st tractor <strong>in</strong>2009; 2nd 2011; began plough<strong>in</strong>g& transport<strong>in</strong>g. Slowly expands,now 14 ha.Ascend<strong>in</strong>g wage labour: LSCF, tosupervisor at Bell tractor co.Funds 3 marriages. Starts cane1997 1 ha, ploughs with cattle;Submits on neighbors code. Slowlyexpands to full fieldsAscend<strong>in</strong>g wage labour:construction ->m<strong>in</strong>er->driver.Returned home to marry & farm <strong>in</strong>1998. Father starts cane 1995 on3ha, gives Mr M 4ha 2001.AZ. switches from miellies tocotton 1 year, then cane withhusband's sav<strong>in</strong>gs. No supp<strong>in</strong>come except mat sales. Slowlyexpands from 1 ha to full field, noextra labour, earned R10--12,000.Covers food & Uni fees for children1991 start 1 ha cane; 1998expand on new 3 ha then other 5.Cane pays for food, college, driv<strong>in</strong>gschool. Husband uses sav<strong>in</strong>g forown-use tractor 1998<strong>Sugarcane</strong> TrajectoryUnclearGett<strong>in</strong>g too old, divided land among6 sons at around 3 ha each. All butone died from 'sickness', cane leftexclusively to widowsStepp<strong>in</strong>g UpEffective cross-sub of contract<strong>in</strong>gand cane; slowly expand<strong>in</strong>g.Drought, few contractors, littlecompetition, now has 50 clients. Butmust travel far; breakdowns oftenStepp<strong>in</strong>g UpRe<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g & cross-sub with cane.Now haul<strong>in</strong>g for approx. 55 SSGs amonth & plough<strong>in</strong>g for hundredsannually. Despite breakdowns, littlecompetition as few contractorsStepp<strong>in</strong>g UpRe<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> contract<strong>in</strong>g; crosssubwith cane. Expand<strong>in</strong>g withdearth of other contractors. Nowapprox. 68 transport & 19 plough<strong>in</strong>gclients. Can now afford extra <strong>in</strong>puts& labourStepp<strong>in</strong>g UpRe<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> land & capital: 2009retires, uses pension to purchasetractor, covers variable costs; 2011purchases 2 ha from neighborHang<strong>in</strong>g InContract<strong>in</strong>g cross-sub cane . Nowhas 30 (plough) and 47 (trans)clients, & 3 tractors, but all broken -> tak<strong>in</strong>g annual loan with 30%<strong>in</strong>terest from local lenderHang<strong>in</strong>g InDecl<strong>in</strong>ed to 4ha, but returned to 6.R8,000 last year, attributes totransport delays. Survives on socialgrants, rest of money for cane andchildren. but expects children willswitch to cattle for lobolaStepp<strong>in</strong>g Out/Diversify<strong>in</strong>g.2008 Drought &high <strong>in</strong>put costs:cycle of decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g returns. Now 1 ha.Reliant on jobs. Seeks alternatives:broilers, gumtree, cattle.
SSG Ward AsstRankTot. LandLandUse AUC Grant Trac Cows LabourIncomeNon-Relation SSG SSGto Hhead Age SexSSGMarryHH CaneSize Year<strong>Natal</strong> home/Arriv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>Madwaleni & ShikishelaBasic Economy/Start<strong>in</strong>g Cane<strong>Sugarcane</strong> TrajectoryMr LG Mad. 4 6 ha 2 ha 2 ha1 PermJob3 CasAgriNo 11Ma<strong>in</strong>lyhomelabourFather 37 M Yes;alive11 1989Born <strong>in</strong> Mad. Father born <strong>in</strong>Shiki, but grandma=sister of<strong>in</strong>duna, granted 6ha plot <strong>in</strong>Mad. food crops & cattle.Father worked <strong>in</strong> DurbanParents start cane <strong>in</strong> 1989, milllabour & tractor ploughs all6ha.Bros seek work on LSCF, butdie of 'sickness' <strong>in</strong> 2000s. LG worksat shell garage ->Uni->BHPStepp<strong>in</strong>g Out/Down?With drought, no mill support, &expense of <strong>in</strong>puts, cane hasdecl<strong>in</strong>ed. Family reliest on grant &LG's good salary.Induna Mad. 1 1 ha ?ha 1 ha 1 temp No 8MixedlabourSelf 70 M Yes;alive16 1989Mad. born. Father=<strong>in</strong>duna,30ha. 13ha cropp<strong>in</strong>g, rest for50 cattle. Leaves home to workas mill technician. Returns <strong>in</strong>1973, assumed title of <strong>in</strong>duna.Land used for cropp<strong>in</strong>g as byself & 3 bros, on around 5 haWages & family cattle, until cattlewiped out.Starts cane <strong>in</strong> 1989 on1.5 ha, expands to 8 ha; bros onapprox 2 ha. Work with sons &some hired labour. Earned aboutR3,000 per ha, to supp food,clothes, school feesStepp<strong>in</strong>g Out/Down?Now only 1 ha to cane: drought &decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g returns, bought less <strong>in</strong>put& labour. Now grow<strong>in</strong>g herd to 10cattle,& is consider<strong>in</strong> us<strong>in</strong>g 1 ha asseedcane.Ms JM Mad. 2 2 ha 2 ha 1 haMrVM Mad. 1 15ha1perm;1 ownbus<strong>in</strong>essYes 164 ha 4 ha None No 5MixedYes;labour Husband 62 F aliveMixedlabourSelf 77 M Yes;alive8 200316 1989CA Homestead elsewhere.Married as 3rd wife to truckdriver <strong>in</strong> Mad., owner of 42 ha.Each wife given 2ha forcropp<strong>in</strong>g, rest for graz<strong>in</strong>g.CA Homestead elsewhere.''Large'' land; not enough tofeed familyleaves to pursuewage work, Comes to Mad.with wife & children <strong>in</strong> 1977,receives 15 ha.Husband contributes wagesmonthly for school fees, food, &agri tools, while wives crop.1990husband buys tractor starts cane.He expands to 12 ha, us<strong>in</strong>g about1/2 the wives land too. Work doneby hired labour & wives.Ascend<strong>in</strong>g wage labour: canecutter, m<strong>in</strong>er, tractor driver. 1984starts cotton, & 1988 buystractor, swiches to cane withneighbor's code. 1991 full 15 haunder cane with FAF ; canesupports family aloneStepp<strong>in</strong>g Down2003, husband stopped giv<strong>in</strong>gmoney to wives. Cane pays for foodand school fees, but less withdrought. Depends on social grants,support from employed son for<strong>in</strong>putsStepp<strong>in</strong>g DownDecl<strong>in</strong>e after drought & end of FAF,extension services. Cannot afford<strong>in</strong>puts, repair broken tractor. Canereduced to 4 ha. First applied forsocial grant <strong>in</strong> 2010Ms NS Mad. 3 8 ha 2 ha 2 ha 1 temp No 0Ma<strong>in</strong>lyunpaidhomelabourSelf 47 FYes;alive4 1995CA Homestead elsewhere. 4ha; mother=domestic; notenough to feed family; nocattle. 1994 marries Gr 12classmate, moves to Mad.Husband already had 8ha undercane, used FAF & worked ascontractor, but 2005 dies <strong>in</strong> carcrash.Dropp<strong>in</strong>g OutDrought + decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g returns,+ 2tractors breakdown, fall <strong>in</strong>production. Income supp by sonwork<strong>in</strong>g as taxi driverMs NB Mad. 25.5ha1.5ha0.5haNone No 5Ma<strong>in</strong>lyunpaidHusbandhome50 FlabourYes;alive4 2007CA Homestead elsewhere. 10ha, 30 cattle, enough tosubsist, but bros migrantlabour. Marries transnetworker, move to Hluhluwe,then Mad, given 5.5 ha.Husband worked, NB uses donkeyto plough food crops, graz<strong>in</strong>g for19 cows. When donkey died, usedpension money to plough & plantcane. Expanded to 4 ha. Paid forfood, clothes, university feesDropp<strong>in</strong>g OutWith drought, high labour/ <strong>in</strong>putcosts (now no poison), cane drops to0.5 ha, meilies 1 ha. Gett<strong>in</strong>g too oldto work (husband bl<strong>in</strong>d), employedchildren do not contribute.Ms MZ Mad. 1 2 ha 2 ha 1 ha None No 3MixedlabourSelf 62 FMad. "Large" land; enough tofeed family large cattle. LeavesYes;dead 10 199? for farm work, marries fellowfarm worker with 3ha plot <strong>in</strong>Mad., 2ha food, 1 ha caneHusband works on game reserve,then SADF <strong>in</strong> 1990s until diabetes,and stops late 90s. Rely on cane,DSG and sell<strong>in</strong>g cows. Mill used tohelp with teams of labourersDropp<strong>in</strong>g Out2000s death of husband and eldestson. Cycle of decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g returns.Receives almost no money fromcane now. Relies on grants; twodaughters employed as clerks
SSG Ward AsstNon-Tot. LandRank Land Use AUC GrantIncomeMs SM Mad. 11 ha(2.5ha)Trac Cows Labour Relation SSG SSGto Hhead Age Sex0 0 None No 0 N/A Self 58 FSSGMarryYes;deadHH CaneSize Year9 1991Ms SN Mad. 2 2 ha 0 0 1 temp No 0 N/A My Child 46 F No 14 1992Ms T Mad. 3Ms K Shiki. 120.5ha2.5ha0.5haMs NS Mad. 1 5 ha 3 haMr ZM Shiki. 1MsMG5.5ha00 00.25 ha4 ha 1.5haMad. 1 3 ha 3 ha 01 Temp3 CasAgri1Sell<strong>in</strong>gmats2 Temp1 Perm1 Cas-AgriNone No 0None No 01 CasAgri1 LandrentalNo 0 N/A Husband 55 FYes;alive19 1997No 0 N/A Self 63 F No 10 1999MixedlabourMixedlabourNo 0 N/ASelf 48 F No 6 1994Self 67 M Yes;aliveGrandmother7 199723 F No 5 N/A<strong>Natal</strong> home/Arriv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>Madwaleni & ShikishelaCA Homestead elsewhere. ''7ha'' land; 12 cattle;father=employed;brother=m<strong>in</strong>er. Marries NPBsecretary. Move to Swazilandbriefly, then Mad.CA Homestead; 4 ha, notenough; mother=unmarriedcasual labour. Parents die,forced to leave, arrive <strong>in</strong> Mad,relatives give 1 ha, work aslocal casual labour.CA Homestead elsewhere. 3 hafor food, no cattle. All sibl<strong>in</strong>gsseek wage work. T works onLSCF, marries Spoornetlabourer moves to Mad. <strong>in</strong>1998CA Homestead Elsewhere. 5ha, 16 cows father =farmworker. Children all seek workas age. Ascend<strong>in</strong>g wage labour,domestic->factory worker.Marries hotel worker, movesto Mad.CA Homestead elsewhere.4ha,10-20 cattlefather=casualtimber labourer Married at 19as 3rd wife, moves to Mad.Husband divides land amongstwives, NS gets 5 haBorn Shiki., parents have 40ha, 400 cows. No-one soughtwage work. Left home after2nd child ('Zulu Custom'),father gives him 3 ha.Mad. born. 3h plot, no crops orcattle. Mother born <strong>in</strong> Mad.Not sure of father.Basic Economy/Start<strong>in</strong>g CaneRely on husband wages, crop on1.5 ha, borrows 6 ha, sells somefood crops. 1991 starts caneUse<strong>in</strong>g husband's sav<strong>in</strong>gs. On 1 ha,not enough profit; expands to 4ha. Covers <strong>in</strong>puts, clothes, schoolfees.SN receives 1 ha from boyfriendbefore he absconds. Still relys oncasual cane work. In 1992, lendsland to contractor to plant cane &take first cut. Cane proceeds buyabout 1 month's worth of foodHusband at Spoornet for 25 years;T would grow food on 0.5 ha &cane on 2ha from 2000-2008, withother 20 ha for graz<strong>in</strong>g. Still doescane work on neighbors farm, butsurvives on private pension &social grants.Husband dies 9 years aftermarriage, as do his brothers. Maworks on cane farm, homesteadsells cotton. By 1999 only Ma &children; starts cane via landrental, but relies on DSG & casuallabour on neighbors cane.Husband was gardener, gave eachwife R100 a month for clean<strong>in</strong>gproducts, but dies <strong>in</strong> 1999. Wivessubsistance crops , and start cane<strong>in</strong> 1994 on 3ha. Earns R14,000;R4,000 profit. Wives reciprocatelabour & hire.Wife cropped, while he soughtwage work: LSCF, clerk; SANDFassistant. Stops 1994. Brother,the <strong>in</strong>duna, grants him an extral 2ha for cane. Pays for <strong>in</strong>itialplough<strong>in</strong>g/<strong>in</strong>puts, then expandswith FAF.Father was m<strong>in</strong>er, but died of'sickness' 2008. Used to do cas agwork with mother, but s<strong>in</strong>ce 2003mom is too sick. Currently rent<strong>in</strong>gland for cane ratoons revert<strong>in</strong>g tothem <strong>in</strong> 2 years.<strong>Sugarcane</strong> TrajectoryDropp<strong>in</strong>g Out1998 husband dies, wages replacedwith R680 pension. No money onhand for fert or labour, brief st<strong>in</strong>twith FAF before ends, cane down to1 ha by 2003. 5 ha revert back toownersDropped OutAs ratoons decl<strong>in</strong>e, exacerbated bydrought; unable to re-plant, orafford <strong>in</strong>puts. Completelydependant on casual labour wagesDropped OutStopped <strong>in</strong> 2008 because of <strong>in</strong>tenseheat, but is consider<strong>in</strong>g restart<strong>in</strong>g,by sav<strong>in</strong>g pension money for <strong>in</strong>puts.First wants soil analysed.Dropped OutCrop established by neighbordepleted. Consider<strong>in</strong>g restart<strong>in</strong>g ifdrought relents and her son helpsbuy <strong>in</strong>puts with his wagesDropp<strong>in</strong>g Out/Creep<strong>in</strong>g Back?Drought + ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>put costs seedecl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g returns; now tooexpensive to replant with grants.Only 0.25 ha to cane. Hopes toexpand by us<strong>in</strong>g current crop asseedcane.Creep<strong>in</strong>g Back?By 2000s, R10,000/ha to re-plant,but earns R8,000/ha. FAF took 20%;& R3-4,000 for consumption.Dw<strong>in</strong>dled to 1.5 ha; 2008 applies forpension. Wants to expand 0.5 ha ata time, re<strong>in</strong>vest proceeds & usesome cutt<strong>in</strong>gs for seedcaneImpoverishedSusta<strong>in</strong>ed by casual agri wages, CSG,& grandmother's pension. Father ofher child work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Empangeni,wait<strong>in</strong>g to marry him, move on hisfamily plot.