13.07.2015 Views

Making The Law Work for Everyone Commission on Legal ... - ISSAT

Making The Law Work for Everyone Commission on Legal ... - ISSAT

Making The Law Work for Everyone Commission on Legal ... - ISSAT

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

In reply to its expressi<strong>on</strong> of sorrow and c<strong>on</strong>cern, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> received a letterfrom Joseph Muturi, <strong>on</strong>e of the market leaders. He wrote that the social fabric builtup over decades had been torn, and that people had been <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced into exile in theirown country, simply because of their ethnicity. ‘We have g<strong>on</strong>e back in time,’ he wrote,and ‘it will take us many years to come back to the level where we were both sociallyand ec<strong>on</strong>omically.’ He observed that it had taken Kenyans to make Kenya; and nowKenyans had broken Kenya; but they would – he was sure – recover it again, althoughat an expense of time and resources that could never fully be regained.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> less<strong>on</strong> is clear. When democratic rules are ignored and there is no law capable ofproviding shelter, the people who suffer most are those who can least af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d to lose.Creating an infrastructure of laws, rights, en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement, and adjudicati<strong>on</strong> is not anacademic project, of interest to political scientists and social engineers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> establishmentof such instituti<strong>on</strong>s can spell the difference between vulnerability and security,desperati<strong>on</strong> and dignity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> hundreds of milli<strong>on</strong>s of our fellow human beings.In his letter from the ruins of the Toi market, Joseph Muturi said that ‘the big taskthat has occupied me is to try to bring the people together in order to salvage oursense of community.’ Creating a sense of mutual resp<strong>on</strong>sibility and community <strong>on</strong> aglobal basis is a key to fighting poverty and a challenge to us all. It is our hope thatthis <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> report, with its recommendati<strong>on</strong>s, will help point the way to that goaland to a better and more equitable future <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> us all.Respectfully,Madeleine K. AlbrightHernando de SotoCo-chairs<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor


AcknowledgmentsSuccess in endeavours of this kind draws from the c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of a very large number ofpeople. We name several of them below and apologise in advance to those whose namesare not menti<strong>on</strong>ed.We acknowledge with thanks the valuable c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s of the working group chairs, rapporteurs,members of the working groups and associated experts.Chapter 1, Access to Justice and the Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, is the outcome of the working groupchaired by <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> member Lloyd Axworthy, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer Minister of Foreign Affairs ofCanada and currently President and Vice Chancellor of the University of Winnipeg.Members and associated experts of the group included Maurits Barendrecht, Nina Berg,Christina Biebesheimer, James Goldst<strong>on</strong>, Robert Kapp, Vivek Maru, Sam Mueller,Clotilde Medegan Nougbode, Richard E. Messick, Kathurima M’Inoti, Wendy Patten,S<strong>on</strong>ia Picado Robin Sully and Matthew C. Stephens<strong>on</strong>, who also served as its rapporteuruntil June 2007 after which the group was supported by Maurits Barendrecht and NinaBerg.Chapter 2, Property Rights, is the outcome of the working group chaired by <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>member Ashraf Ghani, Dean of Kabul University and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer Minister of Finance ofAfghanistan. Members and associated experts of the group included Liz Alden Wily, BanashreeBanerjee, Karol Boudreaux, Wolfgang Bruelhart, Anis Dani, Maleye Diop, SusanaLastarria-Cornhiel, J<strong>on</strong> Lindsay, Sylvia Martínez, Paul M<strong>on</strong>ro-Faure, Edgardo MosqueiraMedina, Rehman Sobhan, Gerardo Solis, and Belinda Yuen. Francis Cheneval, whoserved as the rapporteur, succeeding Robert Mitchell, presented the group’s findings andrecommendati<strong>on</strong>s.Chapter 3, Labour Rights, is the outcome of the working group chaired by <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>member Allan Larss<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer Swedish Finance Minister and currently Chairman of theBoard, University of Lund, Sweden. Members and associated experts of the group includedAzita Berar-Awad, Haro<strong>on</strong> Bhorat, Steven Miller, Jamele Rigolini, Victor Tokman,and Rosanna W<strong>on</strong>g. Sandra Yu served as rapporteur until June 2007, after which MarthaChen and other members supported the group.Chapter 4, Business Rights, is the outcome of the working group chaired by <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>member Medhat Hassanein, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merly the Egyptian Minister of Finance. Members andassociated experts of the group include Martha Chen, Gabriel Daly, Claire More Dickers<strong>on</strong>,S Taher Helmy, Sunita Kapila, Arun Kashyap, Michael Henriques, Tanwir H Naqvi,Enrique Pasquel, Lucas Robins<strong>on</strong>, David Roll, Rehman Sobhan, Gerardo Solis, A JohnWats<strong>on</strong>. Asif Chida served as rapporteur.Chapter 5, Road Maps <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Implementati<strong>on</strong> of Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, is the outcome of the workingi


group chaired by <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> members Hilde Frafjord Johns<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer Norwegian Ministerof Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development, and Milinda Moragoda, Sri Lanka’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer Ministerof Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, Science and Technology. Members and associated experts of thegroup included Maria G<strong>on</strong>zalez de Asis, Christina Biebesheimer, Michael Bratt<strong>on</strong>, DerickBrinkerhoff, Getachew Demeke, Lalanath de Silva, Philip Dobie, Szilard Fricska, TerenceJ<strong>on</strong>es, Daniel Kaufmann, Lily La Torre Lopez, Bruce Moore, Esther Mwaura-Muiru, SheelaPatel, Arjun Sengupta, and Anne Trebilcock. Bibek Debroy served as rapporteur until August2007 and was succeeded by Arthur Goldsmith.Several members of the Secretariat supported the work of the working groups. Specialthanks go to Cate Ambrose and Parastoo Mesri who assisted in the establishment andearly guidance of the groups and also to Ver<strong>on</strong>ique Verbruggen who supervised the workof the working groups from November 2006 to November 2007. We are thankful to themembers of the Secretariat <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their tireless ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts, particularly to Timothy Dolan <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the producti<strong>on</strong> of this publicati<strong>on</strong> and Jill Hann<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Secreteriat management. Specialthanks also go to Kristin Cullis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> her support of our work. A l<strong>on</strong>g list of interns, includingSabiha Ahmed, Shailly Barnes, Wanning Chu, Francesco Di Stefano, Patricia de Haan,Ruth Guevara, Alena Herklotz, Brian H<strong>on</strong>ermann, Emily Key, Rajju Malla-Dhakal, FarzanaRamzan, Erica Salerno, Alec Schierenbeck, Asrat Tesfayesus, Tara Zapp, and Luis Villanueva,supported the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>.Apart from participating as members in our <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>, several multilateral instituti<strong>on</strong>s supportedthe activities of the working groups. ILO hosted meetings of working group three <strong>on</strong>labour and <strong>on</strong>e meeting of working group four <strong>on</strong> business rights, UN-Habitat and the WorldBank provided technical expertise in several areas of the work of the working groups.We are grateful <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the pro b<strong>on</strong>o work carried out by Baker and McKenzie, and Lex Mundi.We extend special thanks to our d<strong>on</strong>ors Canada, Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway,Sweden, Switzerland, Ireland, Spain, the United Kingdom, the African Development Bankand the European <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> whose generous c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s helped to make this <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>a reality and to the in-kind support provided by USAID.We are also grateful to UNDP and its Administrator, Kemal Dervis, , <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> hosting the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>.We are especially grateful the role played by Olav Kjørven and Maaike de Langen.Last, but not least, thanks go to Tevia Abrams <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> his editorial work and Cynthia Spence<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the design and layout of this publicati<strong>on</strong>.Co-chair Executive Director Co-chairii


so that their in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal c<strong>on</strong>tracts have the protecti<strong>on</strong> of the law, and that a safe, secureand equitable way is found <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their integrati<strong>on</strong> within the mainstream ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Thisis c<strong>on</strong>sidered necessary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowering them to derive due benefits from the growingnati<strong>on</strong>al and global ec<strong>on</strong>omy.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> key elements of the strategy to achieve the desired outcomes are as follows:• Create political climate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change.• Synthesize global knowledge relevant to the legal empowerment agenda. To this end,four areas of focus have been identified: Access to Justice and Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, PropertyRights, Labour Rights, and <strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms to Empower In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing groups have been established around each of these themes. A rapporteur ortechnical team-leader, who works closely with the working group Chair (a member ofthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>), to coordinate its work, manages each working group.• Promote the legal empowerment agenda at nati<strong>on</strong>al and regi<strong>on</strong>al level and capturelocal experiences.• Develop policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>s and tools that will guide policymakers in the implementati<strong>on</strong>of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms at the country level.Gender equality and the rights of indigenous communities are central to the legalempowerment agenda. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se issues have been mainstreamed across the work of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>, and specific strategies and recommendati<strong>on</strong>s have been generated in allits areas of work.This is the sec<strong>on</strong>d of two volumes of the report of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor and c<strong>on</strong>sists mainly of the outcomes of five working groups establishedto in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’s deliberati<strong>on</strong>s through substantive work in thethematic areas of Access to Justice and Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Property Rights, Labour Rights,Business Rights and with respect to overall implementati<strong>on</strong> strategies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> workinggroups c<strong>on</strong>sisted of a core of between five and seven experts and stakeholders in theirindividual capacities from around the world, with leading edge expertise and experiencein the theme to be studied.Each chapter is devoted to the findings of <strong>on</strong>e of the working groups and numberedaccordingly.Chapter 1, Access to Justice and Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, focuses <strong>on</strong> how the poor can be legallyempowered and poverty reduced by improving access to justice and expanding therule of law, as defined by nati<strong>on</strong>al views and structures. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> working group c<strong>on</strong>sideredthe top-down and bottom-up processes necessary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> generating effective re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms andpractical recommendati<strong>on</strong>s, and examined the legal tools accessible to all citizens soiv


that they can protect their assets and use them to create trust, obtain credit, captureinvestment, access markets, raise productivity and protect their rights.Chapter 2, Property Rights, examines how the poor can be legally empowered andpoverty reduced when they have fungible rights over property and other assets in atransparent and functi<strong>on</strong>al manner. Because capital has a tendency to c<strong>on</strong>centrate,c<strong>on</strong>tributing to the ec<strong>on</strong>omic exclusi<strong>on</strong> of marginalized groups, legal systems, whichgive the poor access to structured businesses, expanded markets and labour rights arerequired <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their legal empowerment.Chapter 3, Labour Rights, looks into how the poor can be legally empowered andpoverty reduced when the gap between the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is bridgedand labour rights are respected. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> working group studied the factors that c<strong>on</strong>strainparticipati<strong>on</strong> in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and the challenges to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing labour rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>group made practical recommendati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> how to facilitate c<strong>on</strong>vergence between <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maland in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal systems and the en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of labour standards.Chapter 4, Business Rights, studies the factors that preclude the poor from benefitingfrom full participati<strong>on</strong> in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, with a specific focus <strong>on</strong> the regulatoryenvir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> micro, small and medium sized businesses. It also examined localfinancial capacity and incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> lenders to expand access to credit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> individualsand enterprises owned or operated by the poor.Chapter 5, Road Maps <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Implementati<strong>on</strong> of Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, synthesises the key practicaloutputs of the work of the other chapters / working groups into a tool kit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> useby policymakers around the world. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in this chapter draws <strong>on</strong> existing guidelines,frameworks, manuals, indices, indicators and other related aids, which can help thekey audiences of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> and facilitate the implementati<strong>on</strong> of its policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> aim of the tool kit is to support policymakers in proposing re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msand, <strong>on</strong>ce implemented, in measuring their results.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> chapters c<strong>on</strong>tained in this volume reflect the views of the respective working groupmembers, though not necessarily the view of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>.Naresh C. Singh,Executive Director of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>v


Table of c<strong>on</strong>tentsChapter 1 Access to Justice and the Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>......................................... 1Introducti<strong>on</strong> ...................................................................................................... 1An Access to Justice Cornerst<strong>on</strong>e: <strong>Legal</strong> Identity...................................................... 4<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nature of the Problem .............................................................................. 4Addressing the Causes of the <strong>Legal</strong> Identity Crisis: Incapacity,Exclusi<strong>on</strong>, and Avoidance ............................................................................... 5Strengthening the Capacity of the Registrati<strong>on</strong> System ................................... 6Reducing Political Oppositi<strong>on</strong> to Full Registrati<strong>on</strong> .......................................... 9Providing In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and Creating Incentives to Register ............................. 10Strategies to Create Af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable, Inclusive and Fair Justice ....................................... 12<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nature of the Problem ............................................................................ 12<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Social Realities of Access to Justice ..................................................... 12Increasing Quality and Reducing Transacti<strong>on</strong> Costs ...................................... 15Enabling Self Help with In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and Community Organising ....................... 18In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about Norms: <strong>Legal</strong> Educati<strong>on</strong> .................................................. 19Self Help Interventi<strong>on</strong>s: Forming of Peer Groups .......................................... 22Broadening the Scope of <strong>Legal</strong> Services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor ....................................... 23Lower Cost Delivery Models: Paralegals ....................................................... 24<strong>Legal</strong> Services that Empower the Clients ..................................................... 25Alternative Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> ................................................................... 25Bundling with Other Services ..................................................................... 27Removing C<strong>on</strong>stricti<strong>on</strong>s of the Supply of <strong>Legal</strong> Services to the Poor ............... 28Financing of Claims: <strong>Legal</strong> Insurance and Targeted <strong>Legal</strong> Aid ........................ 31Reducing Transacti<strong>on</strong> Costs: Wholesale Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms ............................................. 36Standard Routes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Most Urgent <strong>Legal</strong> Needs ....................................... 37Bundling Claims: Class Acti<strong>on</strong>s .................................................................. 39Other Ways to Reduce Costs of Access Wholesale ......................................... 40Improving In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and Customary Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> .................................... 42Educati<strong>on</strong> and Awareness Campaigns ......................................................... 43Tailored <strong>Legal</strong> Aid Services ........................................................................ 44Targeted C<strong>on</strong>straints <strong>on</strong> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Justice ..................................................... 44Structuring Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Relati<strong>on</strong>ships ........................................................ 45Improving Access to Justice in the Government Bureaucracy .................................... 47<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nature of the Problem ............................................................................ 49Public Administrati<strong>on</strong> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ....................................................................... 49


External M<strong>on</strong>itoring ................................................................................... 49Structural Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms .................................................................................... 50Administrative <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ........................................................................... 53<strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms to Facilitate Participati<strong>on</strong> and M<strong>on</strong>itoring ........................ 53Judicial Review of Administrative Decisi<strong>on</strong>s................................................. 54C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s and Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s ............................................................ 56Chapter 1 Endnotes ..................................................................................... 58Chapter 1 Bibliography ................................................................................. 58Boxes1 Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Justice ........................................................................... 32 Coping with <strong>Legal</strong> Pluralism in Relati<strong>on</strong>s to Women’s Rights in Ethiopia ...... 46Tables1 Needs <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Norms and Interventi<strong>on</strong>s .......................................................... 15Chapter 2 Empowering the Poor Through Property Rights ......................... 63Introducti<strong>on</strong> .................................................................................................... 73Faltering Property Rights: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nature And Scale Of <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Problem.............................. 76Growing Slums and <strong>Legal</strong> Voids ..................................................................... 76Dire C<strong>on</strong>sequences and Missed Development Opportunities .......................... 76Rural Poverty and Property Rights ................................................................. 77Rural Land Relati<strong>on</strong>s and Extreme Poverty .................................................. 77Rural Land Relati<strong>on</strong>s and Armed C<strong>on</strong>flict .................................................... 77Natural Resources ........................................................................................ 77Women Especially Affected ........................................................................... 77Indigenous Peoples ...................................................................................... 78Focus <strong>on</strong> Indigenous Tenure Systems .......................................................... 79Important Numbers of Customary Land Holders ........................................... 79Refugees, Internally Displaced Pers<strong>on</strong>s .......................................................... 80Barriers Versus Facilitators of Change ................................................................. 80Resistance of Powerful Social Actors ............................................................. 80Structural Obstacles and Facilitators of Change .............................................. 80Realising Turnaround .................................................................................. 81Learning From <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Past ..................................................................................... 82Problematic Practices and Omissi<strong>on</strong>s ............................................................ 82Six General Less<strong>on</strong>s from Past Mistakes are Presented as Follows: ................ 82Less<strong>on</strong>s From Mistakes Related to Land and Real Property ........................... 83Experienced C<strong>on</strong>sequences........................................................................ 85Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s For Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m And Improved Acti<strong>on</strong>................................................ 86


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and the Debate <strong>on</strong> Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s ...................... 157<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Impact of Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>: An Overview of Key Results......... 158<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>sequences of Labour Market Regulati<strong>on</strong> ........................................ 159<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Impact of Labour Market Regulati<strong>on</strong>: Country Studies .......................... 161Towards a More Nuanced Understanding of Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s ...................... 162Interpretati<strong>on</strong> of Regulati<strong>on</strong>s .................................................................... 163<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Envir<strong>on</strong>ment .................................................................. 164Heterogeneity in the Regulatory Architecture ............................................. 164C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s............................................................................................... 165Principles and Practices of Labour Rights and <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ................................<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Basis Principles <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Inclusive Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mBoth Promoti<strong>on</strong> of Change — and Management of Change .......................... 166Both Property Rights — and Labour Rights ............................................... 166Less<strong>on</strong>s from Nati<strong>on</strong>al Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Practice ........................................................ 167<strong>Legal</strong> Identity ......................................................................................... 167Voice and Representati<strong>on</strong> ........................................................................ 167Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ......................................................................... 168Improvement of the Quality of Labour Market Instituti<strong>on</strong>s ........................... 168<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment Through Alternative Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> ....................... 169Improved Business Envir<strong>on</strong>ment ............................................................... 169Simplificati<strong>on</strong> of C<strong>on</strong>tracting Procedures ................................................... 169C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nati<strong>on</strong>al Strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ........................... 170Towards a new social c<strong>on</strong>tract: Policies and Processes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment........ 170Policy Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s ............................................................................ 170Process Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s ......................................................................... 173Towards a New Social C<strong>on</strong>tract .................................................................... 175Annex 1........................................................................................................ 176Recent and Current Initiatives to Improve Statistics <strong>on</strong> the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ............... 176Annex 2........................................................................................................ 177Case 1 Extending Thailand’s Labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Through the MinisterialRegulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Home <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers ...................................................................... 177Case 2 Judicial Ruling in the Philippines <strong>on</strong> Employment Relati<strong>on</strong>ship ........... 177Case 3 Welfare Fund in India ...................................................................... 178Case 4 Collective Identity, Collective Bargaining and Global Impact ................ 179Case 5 Federati<strong>on</strong> of Urban Poor Participating in Governance ........................ 180Case 6 Legislative Initiatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Unorganised <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers ................................... 182Case 7 Social Security <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all in the Philippines ............................................ 183Case 8 Minimum Living Standard Security System in China ........................... 184Case 9 Labour protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> subc<strong>on</strong>tracts in Chile ........................................ 184


Case 10 Spain: Flexibility at the Margin ....................................................... 185Case 11 China’s Positive Resp<strong>on</strong>ses to Growing Market Ec<strong>on</strong>omy ................... 186Case 12 Out-of-court Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> as a Practical Tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment ........................................................................................... 187Case 13 Revising bidding and procurement practices in Senegal .................... 187Chapter 3 Endnotes ................................................................................... 189Chapter 3 Bibliography ............................................................................... 191Boxes 1 Different Categories of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers and Corresp<strong>on</strong>ding Challenges ..1412 Relati<strong>on</strong>ships Between In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and Growth: Cross-country Evidence .1423 ILO’s C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Indigenous and Tribal Peoples 1989 (No. 169) 1454 Social case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong> ................................................. 1485 ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s and Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s Pertinent to theIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy .......................................................................... 150Figures 1 Segmentati<strong>on</strong> in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Labour Market .................................. 140Tables 1 Mean Measures of Regulati<strong>on</strong>, by Income Level.............................. 158Chapter 4 Business Rights ........................................................................ 195<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Entrepreneur .......................................................................... 197<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment and <strong>Legal</strong> Identity ........................................................ 198An Integrated Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Approach ................................................................ 199<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Agenda ................................................................................... 200Introducti<strong>on</strong> and Framework ............................................................................. 202Why Business Rights? And Why Now? .......................................................... 203In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses .................................................. 204<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment and Business Rights..................................................... 205Balancing Human Rights and Market-Based Approach ................................... 205Voice, Representati<strong>on</strong> and Effective Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Governance ............................ 206Greater Access to Markets, Goods and Services, and Infrastructure ................. 207Inclusive Financial Services ........................................................................ 207Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Changes ................................................................................. 208Pursuing the Agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Change .................................................................. 209To Sum Up ................................................................................................ 210In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses .................................................. 210In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal-Formal C<strong>on</strong>tinuum ........................................................................ 210Poverty and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy .................................................................... 211In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises ................................................................................... 211In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises and Productivity .......................................................... 212Mapping of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omies .................................................................. 214Women in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy ................................................................. 215


Indigenous Peoples and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses ................................................ 216Empowering In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses ................................................................ 217To Sum Up ................................................................................................ 219Business Rights: Unlocking Barriers/C<strong>on</strong>straints to Empower In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises ............220Barriers and C<strong>on</strong>straints to Business Rights .................................................. 222<strong>Legal</strong>, Regulatory and Administrative Barriers ............................................... 223Costs of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality .................................................................................... 227Rights-based <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ............................................................... 229To sum up ................................................................................................. 230Empowering In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises Through Access to Markets, Goods and Services,and Infrastructure .......................................................................................... 230Improving the Functi<strong>on</strong>ing of Markets .......................................................... 230Increasing Access to Goods and Services...................................................... 232Inclusive Financial Services ........................................................................ 234Microfinance ............................................................................................. 235Savings ..................................................................................................... 236Micro-insurance ......................................................................................... 236Remittances .............................................................................................. 237Public Private Partnerships ......................................................................... 239To Sum Up ................................................................................................ 241Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Changes and <strong>Legal</strong> Tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Difference <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEnterprises — an Evidence-based Approach ..................................................... 242Innovati<strong>on</strong>s which Dem<strong>on</strong>strate Business Rights and <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ....... 244Starting a Business ................................................................................. 244Operating a Business .............................................................................. 247Expansi<strong>on</strong> .............................................................................................. 248En<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing C<strong>on</strong>tracts ................................................................................ 250Exit ....................................................................................................... 251Successful Initiatives taken by Businesses ................................................ 251An Integrated Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Approach ................................................................ 253To Sum Up ................................................................................................ 255Pursuing the Agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Change ....................................................................... 256Changes have to be C<strong>on</strong>text Specific ............................................................ 257Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Processes Must Be Participatory and Gender Resp<strong>on</strong>sive .................... 257<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Business Should be Prioritized as aGgovernance Issue ..................................................................................... 257Strategies and Instituti<strong>on</strong>s to Support In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses ............................ 258Market Based Instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor ......................................................... 259Adding Value and Supply Chain to the Labour of the Poor and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses ................................................................................................ 259


Taking Microcredit Out of the Ghetto ........................................................... 259Mutual Funds <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor .......................................................................... 260Instituti<strong>on</strong>alising the Collective Identity of Poor and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses ........ 261Business Rights - Provides Value Based Change Process ................................ 262Pillars of Change ....................................................................................... 263C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s............................................................................................... 265Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s and Key Messages .......................................................... 266Objectives of Empowerment Process ......................................................... 266Means to Meet Objectives ........................................................................ 266<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Formalisati<strong>on</strong> Debate ........................................................................ 266Chapter 4 Endnotes ................................................................................... 267Chapter 4 Bibliography ............................................................................... 271Boxes 1 Empowering Indigenous People through Entrepreneurship ............... 2172 Unlocking Barriers: <strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms to Empower In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses .................................................................................... 2213 Most Difficult Places to Do Business (by specific category) .............. 2244 Largest Multi-Nati<strong>on</strong>al Company has 2.3 Milli<strong>on</strong> Rural Poor Womenas Shareholders ............................................................................. 260Case StudiesUkraine and Private Business Development ............................................... 226New Markets Lead to New Opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rural In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses—VegCARE, Kenya ..................................................................................... 232Linking Markets: Promoting Sustainable Tourism Development withIndigenous and Rural Communitiesin Latin America ................................... 234Alternate Model of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Credit: SMEs Helping In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises in Peru ..235C<strong>on</strong>strumex (Mexico) — Helping Migrants with Remittances ....................... 238Durban: A Heterogeneous Soluti<strong>on</strong> Through Public Private Partnership ........ 240Buy-back Centres <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waste Collectors: A Public-Private-CommunityPartnership Model .................................................................................. 240“Tell us How to Make <strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms and Tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses.” President Benjamin Mkapa, Tanzania .................................... 243Business Registrati<strong>on</strong> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in Uganda ................................................... 245Identity, Voice And Associati<strong>on</strong> In <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy —A L<strong>on</strong>g Journey Of Self-employed Women’s Associati<strong>on</strong> (Sewa), India .......... 254Technology and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector: Fishing with Mobile Ph<strong>on</strong>es ................ 258Figures 1 GDP Per Capita and the Size of the Shadow Ec<strong>on</strong>omy ..................... 2132 Indigenous Private Sector Development and Regulati<strong>on</strong> in Africa andCentral Europe: A 10-country Study ................................................. 2133 Regulatory Burdens Impacting <strong>on</strong> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises ................... 2234 Regulatory Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality ........................................ 2255 <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises .................................. 263


Chapter 5 Road Maps <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Implementati<strong>on</strong> of Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms:Implementati<strong>on</strong> Strategies, Including Toolkits and Indices ..................... 275Road Maps to Implementati<strong>on</strong> .................................................................... 278Mapping <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment bey<strong>on</strong>d the Nati<strong>on</strong> State .................................. 279Toolkits and Indices ................................................................................... 279Strategy and Tactics ................................................................................... 281Introducti<strong>on</strong>: Attributes of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment .................................................... 283Implementati<strong>on</strong>: Challenges and Opportunities .................................................... 285Policy Initiati<strong>on</strong> ......................................................................................... 287Policy Champi<strong>on</strong>s ...................................................................................... 288Forces Affecting Implementati<strong>on</strong> ................................................................. 289Policy Stakeholders .................................................................................... 290Beneficiaries ............................................................................................. 291Allies ........................................................................................................ 294Practiti<strong>on</strong>ers.............................................................................................. 295Challengers ............................................................................................... 295Policy Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and C<strong>on</strong>textual Analysis ................................................. 296Social Structure ......................................................................................... 296Ec<strong>on</strong>omic C<strong>on</strong>text ...................................................................................... 297Political System ......................................................................................... 298Administrative State ................................................................................... 300In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality ................................................................................................ 302Policy Characteristics ................................................................................. 308Complexity ................................................................................................ 308Ambiguity ................................................................................................. 309Discord ..................................................................................................... 310Diagnosing the Influence <strong>on</strong> Policy Implementati<strong>on</strong> ....................................... 312An Approach to Implementati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Country ‘X’............................................. 312Road Maps to Implementati<strong>on</strong> .......................................................................... 315Mapping the Empowerment Domains ........................................................... 316Mapping the LEP Agenda at Different Political/Administrative Levels .............. 322Activities at Global Level ............................................................................ 323Activities at the Regi<strong>on</strong>al and Sub-regi<strong>on</strong>al Levels ......................................... 324Activities at Nati<strong>on</strong>al Level ......................................................................... 325Activities at the Local Level ........................................................................ 325Country Level Approaches, Toolkits and Indices................................................... 325Countries Piloting <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ............................................. 325Choosing the Appropriate Country Level Process ........................................... 326Tools to Support <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms .............................................. 328


Explanati<strong>on</strong> of the Tools ............................................................................. 328Ready-made Indicators of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ............................................. 328M<strong>on</strong>itoring and Evaluati<strong>on</strong> ............................................................................... 329Strategy and Tactics ................................................................................... 332Strategic Findings ................................................................................... 333Tactical Ideas ......................................................................................... 334Annex 1: Policy Implementati<strong>on</strong> Tools................................................................ 337Annex 2: Existing Toolkits: An Inventory ............................................................. 342Access to jJstice ........................................................................................ 342Property Rights .......................................................................................... 342Labour Rights ............................................................................................ 343Business ................................................................................................... 344Annex 3: Existing Indicators and Indices — An Inventory ...................................... 345Access to Justice ....................................................................................... 345Property Rights .......................................................................................... 346Labour Rights ............................................................................................ 347Business ................................................................................................... 348Chapter 5 Endnotes ........................................................................................ 350Chapter 5 Bibliography ................................................................................... 352Boxes 5.1 Removing Barriers to Public <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>s C<strong>on</strong>tracts .............................. 2865.2 Ancestral Domain Sustainable Development and Protecti<strong>on</strong>Plan of the Bago and Bugkalot Tribes ............................................... 2935.3 Empowering <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers Through Community C<strong>on</strong>tracting ................. 3015.4 Organising out of Poverty: Taxis in Rwanda ................................. 3065.5 Authority Systems: Land Rights ................................................. 3075.6 Gold Rush in M<strong>on</strong>golia: from Herders to “Ninjas”........................ 3205.7 Land Sector Harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong>, Alignment and Coordinati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong> in Kenya ........................................................ 319Figures 5.1 <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor ................................................. 2385.2 Influences <strong>on</strong> Policy Implementati<strong>on</strong>: Empowering the Poor ......... 2895.3 C<strong>on</strong>flict Implicati<strong>on</strong>s of Public Policy ......................................... 3115.4 Road Map to the Implementati<strong>on</strong> Cycle ...................................... 315Tables 5.1 Sample LEP Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms ............................................................... 2855.2 Illustrative Stakeholder Matrix ................................................... 2915.3 Political Administrative Syndromes ............................................ 3035.4 Skelet<strong>on</strong> Diagnostic Tool:Analyzing Influences <strong>on</strong> Policy Implementati<strong>on</strong> ................................. 3135.5 Country Specific Implementati<strong>on</strong> Road Map:Representative Summary Checklist .................................................. 317


5.6 Empowerment Domain 1: Access to Justice ................................ 3185.7 Empowerment Domain 2: Property Rights ................................... 3195.8 Empowerment Domain 3: Labour Rights ..................................... 3215.9 Empowerment Domain 4: Business Rights .................................. 3215.10 LEP Implementati<strong>on</strong> Strategies and Indicative Activities ............ 3235.11 Pro-poor Policy Implementati<strong>on</strong> Tools ....................................... 3305.12 A Framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Demand-led Assessment of Implementati<strong>on</strong> ... 331


1. Introducti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor (CLEP) emphasises re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to the law andjustice sector that will provide poor people withthe instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment, protecti<strong>on</strong>s, andincentives that they need to realise their full capabilitiesand reap the maximum potential return<strong>on</strong> their existing assets. This in turn requires legalprotecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> physical assets (property rights),human capital (labour rights), and the ability toengage in profitable market transacti<strong>on</strong>s (entrepreneurialrights). Poor communities also requirebasic services that cannot be supplied efficientlyin the private market, such as essential utilities,a healthy envir<strong>on</strong>ment, public security, and asocial safety net. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal system must protectaccess to both private rights and public goods ifpoor people are to be able to escape poverty.Poor people tend to live in communities withscarce resources. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> challenge <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the justicesystem, those who govern and their internati<strong>on</strong>alpartners is <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>midable: How to turn the law intoan effective tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> those living in absolute poverty— people living with less than a dollar a day?<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> optimistic goal of our working group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Chapter 1 was to identify promising strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legally empowering poor people to have accessto justice. In the process, we investigated bestavailable practices and solicited suggesti<strong>on</strong>s duringa series of nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s organised bythe <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> (CLEP), and we reviewed evaluati<strong>on</strong>studies of access to justice programmesc<strong>on</strong>ducted by various NGOs. It was apparent thatacademic research had delivered many case studiesabout in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice systems in developingcountries.In additi<strong>on</strong> to the focus <strong>on</strong> practice, experienceand the variety of outcomes, we propose toc<strong>on</strong>sider theory. Although law and developmentis a recognised research topic (since the 1960s),there is as yet no generally accepted frameworkour working group could use <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> analysing accessto justice issues. Many strands of research, however,from instituti<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omics to negotiati<strong>on</strong>theory and from legal anthropology to the analysisof market failure, can yield in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about themost promising strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> providing access tojustice. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and development, operating underthe name of legal empowerment, is <strong>on</strong>e particularstrand the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> could usefully build<strong>on</strong> (Golub and McQuay 2001; Golub 2003), andthere are others using bottom-up perspectives (VanRooij 2007). More generally, bottom-up and empowermentapproaches have been part of the developmentagenda since the late 1990s (Narayan2005), and they have now become building blocksof programmes such as the World Bank’s work inCommunity Driven Development and, more recently,its Justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor programme.In additi<strong>on</strong> to issues of practice and theory, wewill c<strong>on</strong>sider legal principles. It may be difficult2


to achieve access to justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor througha <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice system, but the ideals of the ruleof law are an indispensable part of the visi<strong>on</strong> ofthe legal empowerment agenda. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor requires a society governed bythe rule of law. While the ‘rule of law’ has differentmeanings in different c<strong>on</strong>texts, US Justice Anth<strong>on</strong>yKennedy (a <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>er of the CLEP) hasdefined the rule of law as requiring fidelity to principlesregarding law being superior and binding,n<strong>on</strong>-discriminating, respectful of people, givingpeople voice and their human rights, and effective(see Textbox 1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> his and other definiti<strong>on</strong>s).Rather than attempting a comprehensive surveyor a tailor-made theoretical framework, this chapterfocuses <strong>on</strong> varying aspects of the access tojustice issue. Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 addresses a widespreadand so far underappreciated problem: many poorpeople lack any sort of legal identity or <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallegal recogniti<strong>on</strong>, and as a result they are completelyexcluded from the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal protecti<strong>on</strong>s ofthe state legal system and as beneficiaries ofpublic goods and services. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 turns to thebasic challenge <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> our working group: How canthe justness and fairness of what is delivered beimproved? How can the costs be reduced? Fourstrategies to improve access to justice are discussed.We start at the client end of the supplychain with facilitating self-help and educati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>n we move <strong>on</strong> to the provisi<strong>on</strong> of legal services,the development of procedures that are bettersuited to legal needs and resources of the poor,and the potential of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice.Box 1 Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Justice<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rule of law (….) refers to a principle of governancein which all pers<strong>on</strong>s, instituti<strong>on</strong>s and entities,public and private, including the state itself, areaccountable to laws that are publicly promulgated,equally en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced and independently adjudicated, andwhich are c<strong>on</strong>sistent with internati<strong>on</strong>al human rightsnorms and standards. It requires, as well, measures toensure adherence to the principles of supremacy of law,equality be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e the law, accountability to the law, fairnessin the applicati<strong>on</strong> of the law, separati<strong>on</strong> of powers,participati<strong>on</strong> in decisi<strong>on</strong>-making, legal certainty,avoidance of arbitrariness, and procedural and legaltransparency.(…)“justice” is an ideal of accountability and fairnessin the protecti<strong>on</strong> and vindicati<strong>on</strong> of rights and thepreventi<strong>on</strong> and punishment of wr<strong>on</strong>gs. Justice impliesregard <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rights of the accused, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the interests ofvictims and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the well-being of society at large. It isa c<strong>on</strong>cept rooted in all nati<strong>on</strong>al cultures and traditi<strong>on</strong>sand, while its administrati<strong>on</strong> usually implies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maljudicial mechanisms, traditi<strong>on</strong>al dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>mechanisms are equally relevant. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> internati<strong>on</strong>alcommunity has worked to articulate collectively thesubstantive and procedural requirements <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the administrati<strong>on</strong>of justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> more than half a century(Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Transiti<strong>on</strong>al Justice in C<strong>on</strong>flict andPost-C<strong>on</strong>flict Societies Report of the Secretary-General;S/2004/616 of 23 August 2004).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> is superior to, and thus binds, the governmentand all its officials.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> affirms and protects the equality of all pers<strong>on</strong>s.By way of example <strong>on</strong>ly, the law may not dis-criminateagainst pers<strong>on</strong>s by reas<strong>on</strong> of race, color, religi<strong>on</strong>,or gender.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> law must respect the dignity and preserve thehuman rights of all pers<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> must establish and respect the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alstructures necessary to secure a free and decent societyand to give all citizens a meaningful voice in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulatingand enacting the rules that govern them.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> must devise and maintain systems to adviseall pers<strong>on</strong>s of their rights and just expectati<strong>on</strong>s, andto empower them to seek redress <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> grievances andfulfilment of just expectati<strong>on</strong>s without fear of penalty orretaliati<strong>on</strong>. (Kennedy 2007).3


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical perspectives that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m this analysisare reducing transacti<strong>on</strong> costs, as well as remedyingmarket failure like imperfect in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.Secti<strong>on</strong> 4 addresses the related but distinct issueof access to justice in relati<strong>on</strong> to the bureaucracyof public administrati<strong>on</strong>. It c<strong>on</strong>siders how thepoor can get access to the complaint structuresof the state and the public administrati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>sare drawn in a final fifth secti<strong>on</strong>.2. An Access to JusticeCornerst<strong>on</strong>e: <strong>Legal</strong> Identity 1<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nature of the ProblemOne important basis of legal empowerment is ‘legalidentity’: the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal, legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> by thestate that a pers<strong>on</strong> exists. In developed countries,citizens take this <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> granted. Whether through abirth certificate, nati<strong>on</strong>al ID card, or other means,they are empowered to own property, legally work,c<strong>on</strong>tract to buy and sell goods, receive governmentbenefits, vote, initiate a complaint throughthe channels of public administrati<strong>on</strong>, bring suitin a court of law, or avail themselves of other legalprotecti<strong>on</strong>s.But the situati<strong>on</strong> in many developing countriesis much different. Weaknesses in the managementof birth registries, costly and time-c<strong>on</strong>sumingprocedures needed to register, and otherobstacles can make securing a legal identity achallenge. And a pers<strong>on</strong> without legal identityis denied a whole range of benefits essential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>overcoming poverty. She may be unable to attendschool, obtain medical services, vote inelecti<strong>on</strong>s, get a driver’s license, or open a bankaccount. Moreover, those who lack a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legalidentity are often unable to take advantage ofanti-poverty programmes specifically designed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>them. Those who lack a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal identity may alsobe especially vulnerable to exploitative practices,including child labour and human trafficking.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> importance of providing all people with <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallegal recogniti<strong>on</strong> has l<strong>on</strong>g been recognised.Indeed, the Universal Declarati<strong>on</strong> of HumanRights announced over 50 years ago that, “<str<strong>on</strong>g>Every<strong>on</strong>e</str<strong>on</strong>g>has the right to recogniti<strong>on</strong> everywhere asa pers<strong>on</strong> be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e the law” (Art. 6). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> UniversalDeclarati<strong>on</strong> also affirmed the right of all people to‘nati<strong>on</strong>ality,’ meaning the right to be c<strong>on</strong>sidered a4


citizen of some state (Art. 15). Subsequent globaland regi<strong>on</strong>al human rights treaties have reaffirmedand refined the basic human right to legalrecogniti<strong>on</strong> and nati<strong>on</strong>ality. 2 (It should be notedthat legal registrati<strong>on</strong> and citizenship, thoughrelated, are distinct issues. One can have uncertaincitizenship even in the presence of a validbirth registrati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> primary focus of the currentdiscussi<strong>on</strong> is the issue of registrati<strong>on</strong>, thoughthe issue of citizenship is necessarily also part ofthe discussi<strong>on</strong>, given the close linkages betweenthe issues.)Despite this <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal recogniti<strong>on</strong> of a fundamentalindividual right to a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally recognisedlegal identity, however, the lack of legalidentity remains a widespread problem. Althoughreliable systematic data is limited, the availableevidence suggests that the number of peoplewho lack a legal identity number in the tens ofmilli<strong>on</strong>s (UNICEF 2005). Those without legalidentity are disproporti<strong>on</strong>ately poor, and are oftenmembers of disadvantaged indigenous peoples orother ethnic minorities.In Latin America, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, some estimatesput the number of “functi<strong>on</strong>ally undocumented”Bolivian citizens as high as two milli<strong>on</strong> or closeto <strong>on</strong>e-third of the total populati<strong>on</strong>; in some partsof the country, over 90 percent of the populati<strong>on</strong>lacks a valid <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of identificati<strong>on</strong> (Ardaya andSierra 2002). In Peru, approximately <strong>on</strong>e milli<strong>on</strong>Peruvian highlanders have no legal identity andno legal rights (Axworthy 2007). In several Argentinemunicipalities, some 15 percent of potentialbeneficiaries of an anti-poverty programme wereunable to participate due to the lack of a validnati<strong>on</strong>al ID card (IADB 2006). According toUNICEF (2005), roughly 23 milli<strong>on</strong> South Asianchildren — over 60 percent of all children bornin the regi<strong>on</strong> — are born but not registered eachyear. In Nepal, about four-fifths of all births areunregistered, which means that upwards of fourfifthsof Nepalese citizens may be denied lawfulaccess to educati<strong>on</strong>, employment opportunities,and the political process (Laczo 2003). Thingsare not much better in sub-Saharan Africa: overhalf of all children in this part of the world arenot registered, meaning that each year approximately15 milli<strong>on</strong> children are born without themeans to access either the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy orgovernment-provided social services. Worldwide,approximately 40 percent of children in developingcountries are not registered by their fifthbirthday, and in the least-developed countries,this number climbs to a shocking 71 percent(UNICEF 2005).It is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e no exaggerati<strong>on</strong> to describe thecurrent situati<strong>on</strong> as a worldwide governance crisis.Effective remediati<strong>on</strong> of this crisis requiresboth a diagnosis of its causes and an assessmentof different strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.Addressing the Causes of the <strong>Legal</strong>Identity Crisis: Incapacity, Exclusi<strong>on</strong>,and AvoidanceAlthough no two countries are exactly alike, thelegal identity crisis appears to have three primarycauses:• First, many countries lack an effective bureaucraticsystem <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> providing accessible,reliable, and low-cost registrati<strong>on</strong> services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>all people who would like to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally registerthemselves with the state.• Sec<strong>on</strong>d, in far too many countries the denialof legal identity is the result of a deliberateinterest in excluding certain groups from fullparticipati<strong>on</strong> in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy, polity, and publicsphere. Sometimes this exclusivity arisesbecause of reprehensible discriminatory animus.In other cases, such as those involving5


l<strong>on</strong>g-term migrant or refugee populati<strong>on</strong>s, theproblem is more complex and delicate, and itmay implicate the policies of more than <strong>on</strong>estate. Despite these differences, in all thesecases people are deprived of their fundamentalentitlement to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> becauseof a political decisi<strong>on</strong> to exclude them.• Third, some poor individuals may lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallegal registrati<strong>on</strong> because they choosenot to take the steps necessary to acquireit. This avoidance may seem irrati<strong>on</strong>al giventhe adverse c<strong>on</strong>sequences of lacking a legalidentity. Sometimes this avoidance behaviourmay arise because of an ingrained distrust ofstate authorities. But often avoidance of stateauthority, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong> in particular,may be entirely rati<strong>on</strong>al. Formal legal registrati<strong>on</strong>may also make <strong>on</strong>e more vulnerable totaxati<strong>on</strong>, c<strong>on</strong>scripti<strong>on</strong>, or various <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of undesirablestate m<strong>on</strong>itoring. Thus, governmentpolicy may lead to the legal exclusi<strong>on</strong> of poordisadvantaged communities not <strong>on</strong>ly becauseof a lack of capacity or a deliberate policy ofexclusi<strong>on</strong>, but also because other governmentpolicies create excessive disincentives to registrati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se three categories are not mutually exclusive,nor are the boundaries between them alwayssharp. For instance, the capacity of the bureaucracyto register births may remain weak becausepowerful political interests have an incentive notto fix the problems. This “passive” discriminati<strong>on</strong>is partly an issue of bureaucratic incapacity andpartly an issue of deliberate exclusi<strong>on</strong>. N<strong>on</strong>etheless,this crude tripartite scheme is usefulbecause it underscores the fact that the legalidentity problem has a diverse set of possiblecauses, and proposed soluti<strong>on</strong>s must there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ebe tailored to the particular situati<strong>on</strong>. Proposedre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to the registrati<strong>on</strong> system may be of limiteduse when exclusi<strong>on</strong> results from deliberatepolicy choices. Likewise, high-level political pressureand the entrenchment of n<strong>on</strong>-discriminati<strong>on</strong>norms do not guarantee success when the problemis low bureaucratic capacity. Let us c<strong>on</strong>siderthe three primary sources of the legal identitycrisis and what might be d<strong>on</strong>e about them.Strengthening the Capacity of the Registrati<strong>on</strong>SystemMany government-run civil registrati<strong>on</strong> systemsimpose particularly <strong>on</strong>erous burdens <strong>on</strong> poorpeople. Registrati<strong>on</strong> systems often require registrantsto pay a fee; many will not waive this feeeven <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the indigent. Some registrati<strong>on</strong> systemsalso require that the registrant appear in pers<strong>on</strong>at a registrati<strong>on</strong> office that may be located a significantdistance from a prospective registrant’sresidence. Both travel costs and the opportunitycosts of the prospective registrant’s time mayweigh heavily against registrati<strong>on</strong>, especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>poor people in remote areas with limited disposableincome. And, of course, petty corrupti<strong>on</strong> maysubstantially raise the costs of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong>,as the prospective registrant may have to paybribes as well as official registrati<strong>on</strong> fees. Furthermore,the bureaucratic registrati<strong>on</strong> processitself is often complicated and time-c<strong>on</strong>suming,presenting applicants with a labyrinthine array of<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms and procedural requirements, and the bureaucraticpers<strong>on</strong>nel who run many nati<strong>on</strong>al registrati<strong>on</strong>systems are often insufficient and poorlytrained (Barendrecht and van Nispen 2007).Registrati<strong>on</strong> offices may also lack the most basicresources. For example, surveys of woman in LatinAmerica reveal that approximately 10 percentof women did not register their children becausethe local registrati<strong>on</strong> office lacked the proper stati<strong>on</strong>ary(IADB 2006).A natural first step in redressing the legal iden-6


tity crisis is to reduce the financial and physicalbarriers to access that disproporti<strong>on</strong>ately burdenpoor and rural communities. With respect tothe financial barriers, an obvious re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is theeliminati<strong>on</strong> of fees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registrati<strong>on</strong> and acquisiti<strong>on</strong>of a first copy of the necessary identificati<strong>on</strong>documents. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> usual arguments <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> user fees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>government services do not apply <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal registrati<strong>on</strong>:legal identity is not a scarce resource thata government might legitimately want to rati<strong>on</strong>,nor is registrati<strong>on</strong> a service that people have anincentive to “over-c<strong>on</strong>sume” if they do not bearthe costs of providing the service. Also, most ofthe cost of a registrati<strong>on</strong> programme is the fixedcost of creating and maintaining the necessarybureaucratic infrastructure; the variable cost associatedwith the number of registrati<strong>on</strong> requestsis likely to be relatively small. As between eliminatingregistrati<strong>on</strong> fees altogether and providinga waiver <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor individuals, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer approachis generally preferable as it eliminates the administrativecosts associated with determiningwho is eligible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a waiver. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> costs of operatingregistrati<strong>on</strong> programmes, in most cases, shouldbe met through lump-sum budget allocati<strong>on</strong>smade out of general public revenues rather thanthrough user fees.In additi<strong>on</strong> to eliminating fees, prospective registrantsshould, where possible, be given multipleavenues through which they can register theiridentities, rather than <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing them to rely <strong>on</strong> asingle bureaucratic provider of registrati<strong>on</strong> services.This redundancy might admittedly entailsome administrative costs, but it would yield twosignificant benefits. First, this system would alloweach individual to select the method that is easiestand cheapest <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> her. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, having multipleproviders of registrati<strong>on</strong> services reduces the opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> corrupti<strong>on</strong>, abuse, and delay, becauseprospective registrants will avoid a registrati<strong>on</strong>provider that has a bad reputati<strong>on</strong> (Shleiferand Vishney 1993). As a rough-and-ready ruleof thumb, every individual should always have atleast two realistic, viable opti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registeringherself or her child. Of course, right now manypeople have zero realistic, viable opti<strong>on</strong>s, so goingfrom zero to <strong>on</strong>e would have to be counted animprovement, but two or more would be better.In communities that have the requisite in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>technology infrastructure, it might also bepossible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> private firms, civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s,governments, or some combinati<strong>on</strong> of allthree to set up offices where people can registerthemselves using a simple interactive computersystem, perhaps with assistance from <strong>on</strong>-sitetechnical staff (Barendrecht and van Nispen2007). This alternative may not be realistic <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>all poor communities, but where it is feasible, itmay be a better alternative to relying <strong>on</strong> paper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms and in-pers<strong>on</strong> interacti<strong>on</strong> with governmentbureaucrats. Employing such a strategy, where itis feasible, may free up more resources that canthen be targeted at other communities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> difficulty of reaching poor communities, especiallydispersed rural communities, remains achallenge. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are several strategies that governmentsand interested organisati<strong>on</strong>s might use toimprove the outreach and efficacy of registrati<strong>on</strong>ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts. One strategy is to simplify the registrati<strong>on</strong>process and to improve training of government officialsand others. Another technique that has shownpromise involves the wide distributi<strong>on</strong> of semiportableregistrati<strong>on</strong> kits. In the Democratic Republicof C<strong>on</strong>go, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, UNDP and the UnitedNati<strong>on</strong>s Missi<strong>on</strong> to C<strong>on</strong>go succeeded in registeringapproximately 25.7 milli<strong>on</strong> C<strong>on</strong>golese in 2006 inadvance of the nati<strong>on</strong>al electi<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y did this byusing planes, boats, trucks, canoes, and carts todistribute registrati<strong>on</strong> kits, each of which c<strong>on</strong>taineda laptop computer, fingerprinting materials, and a7


digital camera that could be used to issue photoID cards <strong>on</strong> the spot (Paldi 2006). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Cambodiangovernment used an even more aggressive approachto ‘mobile registrati<strong>on</strong>’: following changes to theCambodian Civil Code that made birth registrati<strong>on</strong>mandatory, mobile registrati<strong>on</strong> teams — run byn<strong>on</strong>-governmental organisati<strong>on</strong>s but with the government’sblessing — have been going door-to-doorto deliver free birth registrati<strong>on</strong>s to people’s homessince 2004. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results have been dramatic: overthe course of <strong>on</strong>ly a few years, the number of registeredCambodian citizens increased from 5 percentto 85 percent (Damazo 2006). A UNICEF-backedprogramme in Bangladesh has employed a similarstrategy, sending trained registrars house-to-house,with similar results: in the ten years since this programmebegan, over 12 milli<strong>on</strong> births have been<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally registered (UNICEF 2006).Another potentially valuable approach to improvingregistrati<strong>on</strong> ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts is to ‘bundle’ registrati<strong>on</strong>with other service delivery programmes. For example,many countries have, or are c<strong>on</strong>sidering,extensive vaccinati<strong>on</strong> programmes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> children inpoor communities. It may often be relatively easy<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the health worker providing the vaccinati<strong>on</strong> toregister each child she vaccinates (ADB 2005).This approach, used successfully in Bangladesh,is more cost effective than financing a separateregistrati<strong>on</strong> campaign al<strong>on</strong>gside the vaccinati<strong>on</strong>campaign <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the same populati<strong>on</strong> (UNICEF2006). In additi<strong>on</strong>, it is c<strong>on</strong>ceivable that themother, and even the extended family members,can be registered at the same time without muchextra ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t, thus profiting from a fitting chainregistrati<strong>on</strong> service. Similarly, some poor women— sadly, not nearly enough — receive some <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mof prenatal care, and some have the assistanceof a health care professi<strong>on</strong>al at delivery. Whilewomen receiving prenatal and delivery care arealready more likely to register their children, empoweringhealth providers to register newbornsmight substantially improve registrati<strong>on</strong> ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts.For example, a pilot programme in large publichospitals in South Africa was successful in registeringlarge numbers of poor children (UNICEF2003). Primary school registrati<strong>on</strong> at enrolmenttime is yet another opportunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registeringchildren who might otherwise lack a legal identityif they had not have been registered at birth.An alternative strategy that might be effective,provided that incentives are well targeted, is outsourcingthe partial or entire registrati<strong>on</strong> processto local stores, banks, and other places were peopleengage in ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities. Similarly, somepoor women — though, sadly, not nearly enough— receive some <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of prenatal care, and somehave the assistance of a health care professi<strong>on</strong>alat delivery. While women who receive prenataland delivery care are already more likely to registertheir children, empowering these healthproviders to register newborns might substantiallyimprove registrati<strong>on</strong> ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts.Another sort of ‘bundling’ strategy might link<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal registrati<strong>on</strong> with traditi<strong>on</strong>al culturalpractices such as naming cerem<strong>on</strong>ies (ADB2005). Just as religious leaders are often empoweredto officiate at weddings and legally validatemarriages, so, too, can religious or communityleaders officiating at childbirth rituals be empoweredby the state to register children. This approachhas the advantage of making registrati<strong>on</strong>seem less like an alien <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality imposed by thestate and more like an integral part of familiarcultural traditi<strong>on</strong>s. A related observati<strong>on</strong> is thatlocal chiefs or community leaders can often serveas a valuable liais<strong>on</strong> between registrati<strong>on</strong> authoritiesand poor communities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> local chief canboth provide in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> to the community anddeal with the state authorities.8


Thus, reaching out to local cultural and religiousleaders, and empowering them to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally registerindividuals, may be a more viable strategythan attempting to expand the state registrati<strong>on</strong>bureaucracy. At the same time, care must betaken not to grant local elites a m<strong>on</strong>opoly <strong>on</strong> theprovisi<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal identity. A useful rule ofthumb regarding registrati<strong>on</strong> is that every individualshould always have at least two realistic,viable opti<strong>on</strong>s.Reducing Political Oppositi<strong>on</strong> to Full Registrati<strong>on</strong>Fee waivers, redundancy, outreach, and bundlingmay all help redress n<strong>on</strong>-registrati<strong>on</strong> that arisesbecause of a lack of bureaucratic capacity, butall too often the denial of a legal identity resultsfrom an explicit or tacit political decisi<strong>on</strong>to exclude certain segments of the populati<strong>on</strong>from full and equal participati<strong>on</strong>. This problemis especially obvious in the case of groups thathave been denied citizenship <strong>on</strong> grounds of theirethnicity or their status as refugees or migrants.Examples of groups that have no <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal citizenshiprights, or very limited ‘sec<strong>on</strong>d class’ citizenshiprights, include the Russians in Est<strong>on</strong>iaand Latvia, the Kurds in Syria, the Palestiniansthroughout the Middle East, the Rohingyas inMyanmar and Bangladesh, the Lhotshampas andBihari in Bangladesh, the Banyarwanda in C<strong>on</strong>go,and the Nubians in Kenya. 3Even in cases that do not involve overt deprivati<strong>on</strong>of citizenship, political c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>smay influence government decisi<strong>on</strong>s toleave barriers to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong> in place. Forexample, in the case of the Peruvian highlanders,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong> could potentially drawlarge numbers of poor indigenous Peruvians intothe political process, posing a potential threatto the incumbent political elites. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally,precisely because the lack of legal identity mayblock access to government social services,politicians may recognise that extensive legalregistrati<strong>on</strong> of the poor may be very expensive,because registrati<strong>on</strong> would put greater demands<strong>on</strong> the public treasury.When legal exclusi<strong>on</strong> derives from a lack of politicalinterest in providing legal identity — or,worse, from an affirmative political desire to denylegal identity — <strong>on</strong>e strategy that is sometimeseffective is to increase the internati<strong>on</strong>al profileof a problem and to identify those countries thatdeprive their residents of an adequate legal identity<strong>on</strong> a discriminatory basis. Such ‘naming andshaming’ approaches may not be effective againstcountries where the interest in discriminatoryexclusi<strong>on</strong> is especially str<strong>on</strong>g or where the interestin internati<strong>on</strong>al reputati<strong>on</strong> is especially weak,but in some cases greater internati<strong>on</strong>al attenti<strong>on</strong>to the issue may help effect a shift in policy. Forexample, internati<strong>on</strong>al pressure appears to haveinfluenced the Thai government’s stance towardthe registrati<strong>on</strong> of the approximately 2.5 milli<strong>on</strong>people living in northern Thailand, most of themmembers of various Hill Tribes, who lack officialregistrati<strong>on</strong> documents and who c<strong>on</strong>sequently aredenied citizenship (Lynch 2005, Lin 2006). Inadditi<strong>on</strong> to country and situati<strong>on</strong>-specific internati<strong>on</strong>alpressure, it would be useful if an internati<strong>on</strong>alorganisati<strong>on</strong>, such as UNICEF, UNESCO, orsome prominent NGO, regularly ranked countrieswith regard to their policies <strong>on</strong> registrati<strong>on</strong>, citizenship,and legal identity. This sort of publicitybasedapproach should be carried out in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong>with more sustained ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to gather reliabledata <strong>on</strong> the scope of the legal identity problem.However, any internati<strong>on</strong>al attempt to addressthe legal identity issue must be sensitive to legitimatestate interests in restricting citizenshiprights, regulating immigrati<strong>on</strong>, addressing <strong>on</strong>goinginternati<strong>on</strong>al disputes, and combating voting9


or social services fraud. Thus, although greaterinternati<strong>on</strong>al attenti<strong>on</strong> and the use of ‘namingand shaming’ approaches may be useful, the internati<strong>on</strong>alcommunity must take care to developits evaluati<strong>on</strong>s and prescripti<strong>on</strong>s through a dialoguewith relevant stakeholders.Another possible approach to combating politicallymotivated legal exclusi<strong>on</strong>s is to bring legalclaims be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e internati<strong>on</strong>al human rights tribunals.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> track record of this strategy is mixed,however: while internati<strong>on</strong>al human rightslitigati<strong>on</strong> has sometimes succeeded in raisingawareness, the tribunal decisi<strong>on</strong>s themselveshave typically not been en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced effectively.While internati<strong>on</strong>al human rights litigati<strong>on</strong> mayhave a place in the broader campaign to addressthe legal identity crisis, it would be a mistaketo presume that politically-motivated exclusi<strong>on</strong>can be cured by litigati<strong>on</strong>. Political problemsdemand a political soluti<strong>on</strong>, and human rightslitigati<strong>on</strong> is useful <strong>on</strong>ly if it is part of a broaderpolitical strategy.More generally, the crisis of politically-motivatedlegal exclusi<strong>on</strong> highlights the need to increasethe relevance and effectiveness of the variousinternati<strong>on</strong>al covenants and declarati<strong>on</strong>s thatestablish the basic human rights to legal identityand nati<strong>on</strong>ality. Part of the problem mightbe attributable to a failure of nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>alpolitical will to make the en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementof these fundamental rights a priority. Anotherproblem might be that most of the existing humanrights c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s and protocols discussgeneral goals or end-states, but do not establishc<strong>on</strong>crete benchmarks or standards by which tojudge compliance ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts. It may there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e beworth c<strong>on</strong>sidering if existing internati<strong>on</strong>al humanrights instruments relating to legal identityshould be supplemented with clear internati<strong>on</strong>alstandards establishing markers by which nati<strong>on</strong>alacti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> legal identity can be evaluated.An alternative or complement to publicinternati<strong>on</strong>al acti<strong>on</strong> might be greater ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts bythe d<strong>on</strong>or, academic, and NGO communities toestablish institutes and foundati<strong>on</strong>s dedicated toraising the profile of the legal identity issue andm<strong>on</strong>itoring state compliance with the obligati<strong>on</strong>to ensure that all people have proof of nati<strong>on</strong>alityand are recognised as people in the eyes ofthe law.Providing In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and Creating Incentives toRegisterEven when opportunities to register <strong>on</strong>e’s legalidentity are available, many of the poor may stillfail to take advantage of these opportunities. Onereas<strong>on</strong> may be because poor people do not knowabout <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong>, or they do not understandthe benefits of a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal identity. Anotherreas<strong>on</strong> may be that the poor are suspiciousof the state and its agents, and this warinessleads them to avoid <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong> even whenit would be in their interests. Yet a third possibilityis their rati<strong>on</strong>al calculati<strong>on</strong> that the expectedcosts of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong> outweigh the benefits.When ignorance or wariness of the state are themajor obstacles, <strong>on</strong>e method of redress may be torely <strong>on</strong> culturally familiar and reliable intermediariesto c<strong>on</strong>vey in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about registrati<strong>on</strong> andto assist with the registrati<strong>on</strong> process. Bundlingof registrati<strong>on</strong> services together with other governmentor NGO services or with traditi<strong>on</strong>al ritualsand practices would be c<strong>on</strong>sistent with this approach.More generally, many successful registrati<strong>on</strong>ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts have relied <strong>on</strong> paralegals, NGOs andlaypeople to assist poor individuals and communitiesin completing the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong>procedure.For example, the Egyptian Centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Women’sRights and other Egyptian civil society organi-10


sati<strong>on</strong>s, with the cooperati<strong>on</strong> of the Egyptiangovernment and some financial support from theWorld Bank, have helped thousands of womenobtain legal identity cards (World Bank 2007). AUNICEF-backed project in Bangladesh run by localNGOs used a similar approach, with similarlyencouraging results (UNICEF 2006). Reliance<strong>on</strong> NGOs and community-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s isparticularly valuable in registering groups (suchas women and traditi<strong>on</strong>ally disadvantaged ethnicminorities), which may be especially wary ofthe state bureaucracy. In additi<strong>on</strong>, there is someevidence that improvements in women’s healthand educati<strong>on</strong> will also improve birth registrati<strong>on</strong>.For example, studies in Latin America havefound that the likelihood a child will be registeredis positively correlated with the mother’s ageand educati<strong>on</strong> (UNICEF 2005). This and relatedfindings suggest that programmes designed toeducate and empower poor women, in additi<strong>on</strong>to their numerous other benefits, may also helpredress the legal identity crisis.which case, instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms and registrati<strong>on</strong>drives may not be helpful; they may evenbe counter-productive if they coerce or persuadepoor people into registrati<strong>on</strong> that is ultimatelyagainst their own interests.Major difficulties arise when poor people avoid<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rati<strong>on</strong>al reas<strong>on</strong>s — <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, avoiding taxati<strong>on</strong>, c<strong>on</strong>scripti<strong>on</strong>, orvulnerability to a variety of state abuses. Ultimately,expanding access to legal identity inthis situati<strong>on</strong> will require either mitigating theadverse c<strong>on</strong>sequences of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong> orincreasing the benefits associated with <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malregistrati<strong>on</strong>, both of which might entail extensivechanges to substantive law or political instituti<strong>on</strong>s.While this barrier to change defies cleargeneral soluti<strong>on</strong>s, it is n<strong>on</strong>etheless important torecognise it as a possibility. Well-meaning observersare sometimes too quick to assume thatthe poor are either ignorant or irrati<strong>on</strong>al whenthey fail to take advantage of an apparentlyavailable government service. It may be thatthis avoidance is both in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med and rati<strong>on</strong>al, in11


3. Strategies to CreateAf<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable, Inclusive andFair Justice<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nature of the Problem<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Social Realities of Access to Justice<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor themselves know best when they needjustice most. <strong>Legal</strong> needs surveys and case studiesdisplay a recurring pattern of situati<strong>on</strong>s inwhich poor people have needs or grievances thatare translated into justifiable claims invokingsubstantive rights (Michels<strong>on</strong> 2007; UNDP Ind<strong>on</strong>esia2007). First, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emost, they need pers<strong>on</strong>alsecurity and guarantees that their physicalintegrity is not threatened. Worries about pers<strong>on</strong>aland physical safety and fear that property or otherassets will be taken by <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce diminish the humanresources people have left <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> seizing opportunities.This also requires legal protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> physicalassets (property rights), human capital (labourrights), and the ability to engage in profitablemarket transacti<strong>on</strong>s (entrepreneurial rights). Poorcommunities also require basic services that cannotbe supplied efficiently in the private market,such as essential utilities, a healthy envir<strong>on</strong>ment,public security, and a social safety net. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalsystem must protect access to both private rightsand public goods and services if poor people areto be able to escape poverty. Protecti<strong>on</strong> of theirproperty not <strong>on</strong>ly requires effective registrati<strong>on</strong>,transparent and accountable land tenure systems,but also protecti<strong>on</strong> against expropriati<strong>on</strong> and proceduresand accessible en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement mechanismsthat resolve c<strong>on</strong>flicts (see Chapter 2). Similarly,their interests as employees and as entrepreneursshould be recognised <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally, as well as protectedagainst attempts of others to take advantage oftheir ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts (see Chapters 3 and 4).Surveys c<strong>on</strong>sistently show that the needs ofindividuals <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal interventi<strong>on</strong>s are c<strong>on</strong>centratedaround the major transiti<strong>on</strong>s or changesin pers<strong>on</strong>al status in a lifetime. A likely reas<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this is that property and other assets oftenaccrue within a relati<strong>on</strong>ship. This is especiallytrue <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir homes usually bel<strong>on</strong>gto families and kinships. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y make use of theirarable land where the different members are designateddifferent tasks, roles and rights, whilst<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal officially recognised ownership is uncleareven though a clear in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal regime may exist.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y work in businesses as employees, but alsoas spouse, as a nephew, or as business partner.Communities jointly own pastures, share water,and use the same fishing grounds. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se closerelati<strong>on</strong>ships are powerful tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> value creati<strong>on</strong>,but they also build <strong>on</strong> inter-dependent relati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> partners are tied to each other by specificinvestments, which will be lost if they leave therelati<strong>on</strong>ship (Williams<strong>on</strong> 1985). And often thepoorest pers<strong>on</strong> will have more to loose: tenantsand employees tend to invest more in this specificpiece of land or in the business, than thelandlord or the employer invests in their pers<strong>on</strong>.Women often invest more time and ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t in thefamily and its assets than their husbands. Thatmakes it difficult to leave the relati<strong>on</strong>ship, andmakes them vulnerable to exploitati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal (modern) legal system, with its focus<strong>on</strong> the individual and not <strong>on</strong> a more or lessstr<strong>on</strong>gly defined collective entity, which is alsomirrored in how ownership is c<strong>on</strong>strued, oftendiscriminates against poor people or excludesthem de facto. In some societies, property thatdoes not clearly bel<strong>on</strong>g to an individual will beregarded as state property (see Chapter 2). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>assumpti<strong>on</strong> that c<strong>on</strong>tracts are the <strong>on</strong>ly meansthat allocate residual ownership to <strong>on</strong>e of thepartners in the relati<strong>on</strong>ship equally works against12


the poor. Usually, they do not <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally regulatetheir relati<strong>on</strong>ships. Even in developed countries,marriages, land use arrangements, and the relati<strong>on</strong>shipsaround small businesses are often notdealt with in c<strong>on</strong>tracts, out of c<strong>on</strong>venience, mutualtrust or because it is impossible to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eseeevery c<strong>on</strong>tingency.Thus, the most serious legal problems thatthe poor report in legal needs surveys revolvearound transiti<strong>on</strong>s in these relati<strong>on</strong>ships. Deathof the head of the family, divorce, terminati<strong>on</strong> ofland use relati<strong>on</strong>ships, terminati<strong>on</strong> of employment,leaving a community (selling property), changesin business relati<strong>on</strong>ships, and expropriati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>property development are the most comm<strong>on</strong> transiti<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se transiti<strong>on</strong>s do not <strong>on</strong>ly create problemsof divisi<strong>on</strong> of property, but also do so in asetting that is likely to lead to c<strong>on</strong>flict. This is particularlytrue in areas with scarce natural resourcesand high populati<strong>on</strong> growth where poor familiescannot create sufficient extra value between transiti<strong>on</strong>sto the next generati<strong>on</strong> to make up <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thegrowth in numbers of mouths that have to be fed.In post c<strong>on</strong>flict z<strong>on</strong>es, and in areas struck by naturaldisaster, dislocated pers<strong>on</strong>s need to find propertywhere they can rebuild their lives. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> claimsof those returning home create extra transiti<strong>on</strong>problems and thus legal needs.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> paths to justice available to the poor in orderto cope with these problems and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> accessingtheir rights often develop sp<strong>on</strong>taneously. Communitiestend to organise social structures that dealwith c<strong>on</strong>flict. Within days from the setting upof a refugee camp, the inhabitants create socialnorms and start addressing certain individualswith their grievances. Where a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong>system is lacking, some pers<strong>on</strong> may start collectingin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about who owns which pieceof land and make these data available to others(see Chapter 2). Sometimes these structures willmirror structures from their home areas becausewhole communities have been moved to thesame locati<strong>on</strong>s. Or such structures are of a morepractical nature then reflecting <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malprinciples of justice or customary normative systems.Whether the disadvantaged can use themsuccessfully to deal with their problems is variableand depends <strong>on</strong> access to resources, powerrelati<strong>on</strong>s and other factors. Another opti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor is often present in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of religiousnorms and faith based dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> scope of these mechanisms may belimited, however, to family issues and crime.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are less likely to extend to property rights,employment problems, and the issues related tosetting up businesses <strong>on</strong> which the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor focuses.In some communities, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>mechanisms exist. A recent survey of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maljustice systems identified the following comm<strong>on</strong>characteristics of these systems (Wojkowska2006). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> problem is viewed as relating to thewhole community as a group — there is str<strong>on</strong>gc<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the collective interests at stakein disputes. Decisi<strong>on</strong>s are based <strong>on</strong> a process ofc<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is an emphasis <strong>on</strong> rec<strong>on</strong>ciliati<strong>on</strong>and restoring social harm<strong>on</strong>y. Arbitratorsare appointed from within the community <strong>on</strong> thebasis of status or lineage. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is often a highdegree of public participati<strong>on</strong>. Rules of evidenceand procedure are flexible and no professi<strong>on</strong>allegal representati<strong>on</strong> is needed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> process is voluntary,although there is frequently a lot of pressureinternally in the family or other groups <strong>on</strong>the ‘victim’ to be part of the process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> decisi<strong>on</strong>is based <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sensus, providing a high levelof acceptance and legitimacy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are no cleardistincti<strong>on</strong>s between criminal and civil cases,and between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice systems and localgovernance structures. En<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of decisi<strong>on</strong>s13


is secured through social pressure or more organisedstructures invoked to ensure that parties tothe c<strong>on</strong>flict abide by the comm<strong>on</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong>.Because these systems have been studiedmore intensively than the loose sp<strong>on</strong>taneousordering that has been discussed above, more isknown about their weaknesses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se often workagainst the poor. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal systems tend to rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceexisting power structures. Because they arebased <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sensus, women and disadvantagedgroups may not be assisted to overcome differencesin power levels. Mediated settlements can<strong>on</strong>ly reflect “what the str<strong>on</strong>ger is willing to c<strong>on</strong>cedeand the weaker can successfully demand.”(Wojkowska 2006). And sometimes local normssuggest soluti<strong>on</strong>s that are clearly against the interestsof the weakest (they are regularly all poor).For those living <strong>on</strong> less than $1 a day, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallegal system is often out of reach. As we haveseen, fees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> birth registrati<strong>on</strong> can already be unaf<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable,and a court acti<strong>on</strong> to protect propertyrights or to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce a c<strong>on</strong>tract with a tenant is outof the questi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>ly dealings the poor mayhave with the official justice system may be asdefendants in criminal cases, in which they willnormally have to cope without legal representati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y may suffer from bureaucratic proceduresand red tape (see Chapters 2, 3 and 4), or frompolice abuse. On the other hand, if the poor livein a country that has a functi<strong>on</strong>ing legal system,the influence of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal rules and the threatof interventi<strong>on</strong> by neutral courts, even if just aremote possibility, should not be underestimated(Kauffmann 2003).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> actual situati<strong>on</strong> from which processes improvingaccess to justice have to start can be summarisedas follows. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor have legal grievancesand are even more likely to have such grievances,because of the scarcity in which they live andbecause they are more likely to be dependent <strong>on</strong>others that are more powerful. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y may havesome opti<strong>on</strong>s to access their rights, throughsp<strong>on</strong>taneous arrangements, through faith-basedsystems, through in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice, or through the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system. But through these opti<strong>on</strong>s,taken jointly, they are unlikely to obtain fair andjust outcomes against reas<strong>on</strong>able cost.Starting with the legal needs of the poor is essentialin a legal empowerment approach. Suchan analysis can clarify which elements of the ruleof law are particularly important <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor andto which neutral interventi<strong>on</strong>s they need access.Targeting the most comm<strong>on</strong> legal needs can helpto make legal instituti<strong>on</strong>s more resp<strong>on</strong>sive. Attemptsto improve access to justice are less likelyto succeed if they aim at access to criminal andcivil justice in the abstract. Justice is costly toprovide and priority setting is essential. Table 1highlights some likely priorities, and shows inwhich parts of this chapter these are discussed.It takes the perspective of individuals needinglaw to protect them and to solve their disputes,rather than the perspective of the lawyer who appliesrules. Which norms do poor people need toknow and to apply, and which interventi<strong>on</strong>s canhelp them?Seen from this side, many norms (like the <strong>on</strong>esprotecting property against theft, and life againstmurder) are self-evident, whilst other norms mayyet need to be <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med, or interpreted to becomeeasily applicable (such as the <strong>on</strong>es <strong>on</strong> divisi<strong>on</strong> orcompensati<strong>on</strong> in property disputes or <strong>on</strong> terminati<strong>on</strong>of an employment c<strong>on</strong>tract). Likewise, theneeds <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> interventi<strong>on</strong>s may be different. Seenfrom the perspective of the poor, criminal actsshould perhaps primarily be deterred, problems in<strong>on</strong>going relati<strong>on</strong>ships should primarily be settledin a fair and just manner, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> commercial transacti<strong>on</strong>ssimple en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of debts may be the14


Table 1 Needs <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Norms and Interventi<strong>on</strong>sPers<strong>on</strong>al security and property protecti<strong>on</strong>> Mainly criminal law, notcovered in this chapterIdentifi cati<strong>on</strong> of pers<strong>on</strong>, property,business (registrati<strong>on</strong>) >See Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 of this chapterIssues within l<strong>on</strong>g term relati<strong>on</strong>shipsin which the poor invest (entrepreneurial,family, land-use, employment,community) >Secti<strong>on</strong> 3Market transacti<strong>on</strong>s (debt, credit,c<strong>on</strong>sumer) > Secti<strong>on</strong> 3Protecti<strong>on</strong> against unfairgovernment interference (police,detenti<strong>on</strong>, other) >Secti<strong>on</strong> 4Problems arising out of failure ofgovernment to per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m positiveduties > Secti<strong>on</strong> 4NormsResp<strong>on</strong>sibility to protectRespect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> others’ human rightsRules that deal with standard complicati<strong>on</strong>sefficientlyDefault rules <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fair treatment duringrelati<strong>on</strong>shipRules of thumb <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> divisi<strong>on</strong> of assets atterminati<strong>on</strong>Rules regarding reas<strong>on</strong>able qualityexpectati<strong>on</strong>sSimplifi ed c<strong>on</strong>tractual regimesRegulati<strong>on</strong> of government c<strong>on</strong>ductRespect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> human rightsNorms relating to positive dutiesInterventi<strong>on</strong> capacityGeneral preventi<strong>on</strong> strategiesRetributive/restorative/criminaljustice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> most serious crimesRegistrati<strong>on</strong> capacity that serves theentire populati<strong>on</strong>A setting that facilitates settlement,with:A credible threat of a neutral interventi<strong>on</strong>(settlement in the shadow of the law)Self-en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement through reputati<strong>on</strong>mechanismsEn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of simple c<strong>on</strong>tractsComplaint procedures with independenten<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementResp<strong>on</strong>sive governmentComplaint procedurespriority, and complaints against government mayhave to be used primarily as a tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> creatingmore resp<strong>on</strong>sive government. But any strategy toimprove access to justice should start from a thoroughanalysis of the particular needs in the localsituati<strong>on</strong>, as well as an inquiry into the way thelocal instituti<strong>on</strong>s already fulfil them.An analysis like this not <strong>on</strong>ly shows what the ruleof law and access to justice look like from theperspective of the poor. It also makes clear thattheir demands <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> justice are not unlimited orunrealistic. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor need some norms in particularto protect them and to give them opportunities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y do not need a court or lawyers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> everyproblem that they have in relati<strong>on</strong> to other people,but in some situati<strong>on</strong>s they are vulnerable.In relati<strong>on</strong>ships in which they are dependent <strong>on</strong>others, they need a credible threat of an interventi<strong>on</strong>by a neutral and trustworthy pers<strong>on</strong>. Similarly,their human rights and their c<strong>on</strong>tractualrights should be backed up by the possibility ofen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement. Like other people, the poor tend tosettle their problems themselves. But like peoplewho live under a more effective legal system, theyneed the shadow of law to get access to fair andjust settlements of their differences.Increasing Quality and Reducing Transacti<strong>on</strong>Costs<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong> that poor people have unmetlegal needs does not, however, adequately diagnosethe problem to be solved, nor does it provide15


sufficient guidance as to the best soluti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this is three-fold. First, access to legalservices — and, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> that matter, access to justice— is not valuable in and of itself. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal systemis a means <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improving social welfare andsocial justice. Justice services are valuable insofaras they advance those underlying goals. Sec<strong>on</strong>d,justice services are a scarce and costly resource,and like any scarce resource, they must be producedand allocated efficiently. Third, while poorpeople c<strong>on</strong>sume fewer justice services than isoptimal from a social welfare perspective, this istrue of most goods and services that the poor wantto c<strong>on</strong>sume. Poor people have unmet legal needs,but they also have unmet needs <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> food, clothing,shelter, land, medical care, transportati<strong>on</strong>, credit,leisure time, and virtually every other scarce resource.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Every<strong>on</strong>e</str<strong>on</strong>g> who advocates spending socialresources <strong>on</strong> providing justice services to the poorshould there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e be required to explain why accessto justice should be a priority.As a thought experiment, it is instructive to c<strong>on</strong>siderwhether it would not be better simply totake the amount spent <strong>on</strong> an access to justiceprogramme and give it directly to poor people inthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of a cash transfer. After all, if the poorrecipient is most in need of legal services, shecan spend the transfer <strong>on</strong> such services. If sheneeds something else more, then she can allocatethe transfer to that need instead. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> point is notthat general redistributi<strong>on</strong> in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of welfarebenefits should always be preferred to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mstargeted specifically at justice services. Rather,thinking about the comparis<strong>on</strong> to general redistributi<strong>on</strong>is useful because it <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces the analystto approach the problem of access to justice interms of what can be improved in the system ofdelivery of such services rather than in terms of‘unmet need’.Applied to access to justice, the challenge canthus be phrased in the following terms. Start withinvestigating the legal needs of the poor, thenlook <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> strategies that increase the quality ofwhat people get when they try to obtain accessto justice, and decrease the costs. Phrased inthese terms, the size of this challenge becomesapparent. In order to ensure that legal servicesreach the poor, quantum jumps in price/quality(Prahalad and Hart 2002) should be achieved.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> case study presented in Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 regardingaccess to legal identity shows how difficult thiscan be in practice. Even a procedure that aimsto register simple data and provide citizens withmeans to prove their identity is difficult to organisein a way that effectively reaches out to thepoor. Fortunately, it also shows where strategiesto improve access may be located.First, users weigh the costs of access againstexpected benefits. If costs are higher thenbenefits, they are not likely to register. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>secosts can have many different <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. A motherwanting to register her five-year-old child mayhave to travel, pay fees, spend time to obtaindocuments, or c<strong>on</strong>sult a specialist in legal services.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> benefits of accessing the procedurecan be huge. A child obtaining a registrati<strong>on</strong> isallowed to go to school or can get health care.Similarly, resolving a dispute about water withina community may lead to better use of land thathas to be irrigated and lead to improved, morestable and more productive relati<strong>on</strong>ships. However,as the example of access to identity registrati<strong>on</strong>shows, there can be hidden disadvantages.Claiming rights may increase <strong>on</strong>e’s visibility asan object of exploitati<strong>on</strong>, or as a citizen that hasto pay tax without corresp<strong>on</strong>ding benefits. Thus,access to justice will not materialise unless itsbenefits outweigh its costs.Next, in order to organise access to registrati<strong>on</strong>services, a quite substantive government infra-16


structure is necessary. This is even more so <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the complex interventi<strong>on</strong>s of the legal system.Establishing the rule of law requires a smooth interacti<strong>on</strong>of many different instituti<strong>on</strong>s that cooperateto per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m complicated tasks. A functi<strong>on</strong>inglegal system has mechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> lawmaking inplace, but also <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> facilitating settlement, neutralfact-finding, neutral decisi<strong>on</strong>s in disputes, anden<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of rights. Police, courts, pris<strong>on</strong>s,lawyers, and clients themselves <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m a very complicatedsupply chain. This is also true to someextent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal systems. What its clients getdepends <strong>on</strong> local mechanisms that create socialnorms, the possibilities to challenge them if necessary,the quality of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um that deals withtheir grievances, and the local ways of acceptingand implementing decisi<strong>on</strong>s.What helps, is to give people choice. Multiplepoints of access do not <strong>on</strong>ly liberate the poor inthe sense that they increase the odds that interventi<strong>on</strong>sfit their problems. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also trigger aninnovati<strong>on</strong> process in which it becomes transparentthat the poor prefer some ways of delivering justiceservices above others. This gives service providersincentives to improve what they deliver. Choicesare already part of the realities of access to justice.People have choices between access to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malprocedures and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <strong>on</strong>es. Choices between different<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> (ADR)and choices between settlement and decisi<strong>on</strong> bya neutral party. Although having more choice caninitially lead to higher costs in the search <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themost appropriate approach, it is a sure way, in thel<strong>on</strong>g run, to empower the poor. Finally, choice is aweap<strong>on</strong> against the new dependencies a legal systemcreates. Instead of depending <strong>on</strong> their opp<strong>on</strong>ent,disputants become dependent <strong>on</strong> professi<strong>on</strong>alswith a dedicated and protected positi<strong>on</strong>: governmentofficials, licensed lawyers, official judges,or the powerful in their community. Increasedchoice may be the answer to the m<strong>on</strong>opolies thatcome with official positi<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> case of registrati<strong>on</strong> also shows in which directi<strong>on</strong>to search <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> approaches to reduce thecosts of legal services. Interactive computer systemsthat let people per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m some registrati<strong>on</strong>tasks themselves, mobile registrati<strong>on</strong> units, andbundling registrati<strong>on</strong> with other services are butexamples of a more general class of opportunities.In the European Middle Ages, kings andnobles travelling the country were offering mobiledispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> services. Social workers helppeople to sort out the problems of life, and maybundle this with valuable pieces of legal advice.Filing grievances <strong>on</strong>line can save travel costs andthe costs of intake by professi<strong>on</strong>als. If citizensobtain access to the right in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, self-helpcan not <strong>on</strong>ly empower them, but also relieve thesupply chain of costly tasks.A related less<strong>on</strong> from the registrati<strong>on</strong> example isthat it shows how liais<strong>on</strong>s can be <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med. A legalsystem functi<strong>on</strong>s by <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ging productive links: between<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal; between governmentservices and services provided by the market;between settlement negotiati<strong>on</strong>s and the shadowof a neutral decisi<strong>on</strong>; between clients and professi<strong>on</strong>als.Rule of law is a combinati<strong>on</strong> of publicgoods (laws, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, neutral interventi<strong>on</strong>s bypolice and courts) and services delivered by privatesuppliers (private safety measures, self help,legal services, neutral interventi<strong>on</strong>s from ADR,local justice, religious instituti<strong>on</strong>s).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> last less<strong>on</strong> is that politics matters. Exclusi<strong>on</strong>or limiting access can be profitable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <strong>on</strong>esalready inside the system, as the examples aboutethnic groups that are denied legal identity show.One way or the other inclusi<strong>on</strong> should be mademore attractive <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> insiders. Naming, shaming,or other sancti<strong>on</strong>s can achieve this, and probably17


even better, by showing the <strong>on</strong>es with power thebenefits of increased security, or of a larger classof prosperous customers.This analysis also suggests which theoretical c<strong>on</strong>ceptsand strands of empirical knowledge can behelpful to improve access to justice:- Political ec<strong>on</strong>omy and sociology can help toidentify the deals that have to be <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ged inorder to facilitate inclusi<strong>on</strong>.- <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> image of delivery of justice through asupply chain, points towards the perspectivesof transacti<strong>on</strong> costs ec<strong>on</strong>omics and logistics(supply chain management).- <strong>Legal</strong> anthropology, law and sociology, negotiati<strong>on</strong>theory, c<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong> theory andgame theory can yield valuable in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>about the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> of envir<strong>on</strong>ments thathelp people to settle their differences.- Removing barriers to justice and the similaritiesto the delivery of health care or educati<strong>on</strong>,suggest remedies that emphasise the efficientcorrecti<strong>on</strong> of market failures (Shavell 1997,Barendrecht and van Nispen 2007). While the‘unmet legal needs’ framework typically leadsdirectly to proposals to increase legal aid subsidiesor build a better <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal infrastructure,the market failure framework both offersmore guidance <strong>on</strong> how to allocate scarcelegal aid subsidies and suggests other sorts ofstructural re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that can improve access tojustice.- Knowing that the supply of justice is not apure market transacti<strong>on</strong>, but involves publicgoods as well, and requires a substantial neutralinfrastructure invites the perspectives ofgovernment failure and of public management.- Many of the issues discussed above, and thelinks between access to justice and ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment, are topics studied by new instituti<strong>on</strong>alec<strong>on</strong>omics, a body of thought thatemphasises the importance of public sectorinstituti<strong>on</strong>s, including the legal system, ingenerating ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, and also focuses<strong>on</strong> transacti<strong>on</strong> costs (North 1990).As we proceed with this secti<strong>on</strong>, we will discussfour strategies to improve access tojustice that have proven their value in practice,or seem to be particularly promising, and linkthem to these theoretical c<strong>on</strong>cepts. Our focuswill be <strong>on</strong> the need to resp<strong>on</strong>d to the essentialchallenge: how can the justness and fairness ofwhat is delivered be improved, and, in particular,how can costs are decreased? For this reas<strong>on</strong>, thereducti<strong>on</strong> of transacti<strong>on</strong> costs figures prominentlyin our analysis.We start at the client end of the supply chain,with c<strong>on</strong>cerns about facilitating self-help, educati<strong>on</strong>,and with the theoretical c<strong>on</strong>cept of imperfectin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>n we turn to the provisi<strong>on</strong>of legal services, using primarily a market failureperspective. Following this we will review strategiesto develop procedures that are better suitedto the legal needs and the resources of the poor.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> potential of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice, and its links tothe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system, are discussed at the endof this secti<strong>on</strong>.Enabling Self Help with In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>and Community OrganisingFor a pers<strong>on</strong> with limited resources trying to getaccess to justice, the first (and sometimes the<strong>on</strong>ly) opti<strong>on</strong> is to decide what she can do herself.Her time may be less scarce than m<strong>on</strong>ey. If shecan find ways to solve the problem without payinglegal fees that is what she will tend to prefer. Soa first strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment may be toenhance the possibilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-help in the areaof access to justice.18


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Group has noted that this is a topicthat has not yet attracted sufficient attenti<strong>on</strong> inacademic thinking about access to justice. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reis a certain tendency to equate access to justicewith access to legal services, assuming that the<strong>on</strong>ly road to justice leads through lawyers andcourts. This is rapidly changing, however, nowthat even the Western world discovers that manypeople appear in courts without legal representati<strong>on</strong>and that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about legal rights anddispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> is an essential tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment,as well as <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> preventi<strong>on</strong> of social strife.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> UK government even set up a Public <strong>Legal</strong>Educati<strong>on</strong> and Support (PLEAS) Task Force. Atthis stage, however, the available in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> islimited, and this is certainly an issue <strong>on</strong> whichfurther research is warranted.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about Norms: <strong>Legal</strong> Educati<strong>on</strong>Within this strategy that encourages self-help,know-how about legal norms is essential. Poorpeople may not receive the protecti<strong>on</strong> or opportunitiesto which they are legally entitled becausethey do not know the law or do not know how togo about securing the assistance of some<strong>on</strong>e whocan provide the necessary help. This lack of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>engenders vulnerability to exploitati<strong>on</strong> andabuse, and impedes legal empowerment (NCLEPKenya 2007, NCLEP Philippines 2007). In manydeveloping countries, simply finding out whatthe law is can be a time-c<strong>on</strong>suming and costlyendeavour. In Bangladesh, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance, the government<strong>on</strong>ly publishes a small number of copiesof the statutes passed by Parliament, and thesewere available <strong>on</strong>ly to those who pay a fee. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>few public libraries in Bangladesh suffer from anacute shortage of legal resources (Afroz 2006).In Tajikistan, new statutes are typically published<strong>on</strong>ly in the Parliamentary Gazette, which is notwidely accessible, and ministerial decrees arenot published at all. This makes the simple taskof figuring out what the law is a time-c<strong>on</strong>sumingchore even <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a trained legal professi<strong>on</strong>al (ADB2002). Furthermore, many countries draft andadminister the law <strong>on</strong>ly in the nati<strong>on</strong>al language(often the language of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer col<strong>on</strong>ial government),which many of the poor do not speak. Thislanguage barrier creates a significant transacti<strong>on</strong>cost <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people who might otherwise availthemselves of the legal system. 4An obvious way to remedy this is to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m peoplemore broadly about norms and interventi<strong>on</strong>s thatthey may have to rely <strong>on</strong>. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> technologyis arguably the most promising avenue <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>this, now that the poor will increasingly have accessto internet c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s close to the placeswhere they live. Preferably, such in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>must address the practical priorities of specificpopulati<strong>on</strong>s. Street vendors want to know whichspecific regulati<strong>on</strong>s allow them to ply their trade;what specific lawyers, government offices or n<strong>on</strong>governmentalorganisati<strong>on</strong>s (NGOs) they can goto <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> help if police harass them; or how to press<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of laws that have not yet <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisedtheir status and protected their livelihoods. C<strong>on</strong>versely,women living in societies in which thelaws discriminate against them may be interestedin c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al provisi<strong>on</strong>s or internati<strong>on</strong>al humanrights treaties that at least provide a basis<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> hope, c<strong>on</strong>fidence and activism in favour ofequal rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> should also begeared towards the best practices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> solving theproblems the poor face. What are the rules andthe best ways <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> solving inheritance problems? Afarmer working <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> years <strong>on</strong> a plot of land who isc<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>ted by others who show him a deed thatseems to prove their property-rights will probablywant to know the going rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> settling such aproblem, instead of getting abstract in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>from the civil code about property and leasingc<strong>on</strong>tracts (Barendrecht and Van Nispen 2007).19


A related opti<strong>on</strong> is teaching the poor abouttheir rights. It can show them that the law is<strong>on</strong> their side, or that it is deficient and shouldbe changed, or that they should be c<strong>on</strong>fidentin pressing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of bad laws or theimplementati<strong>on</strong> of good <strong>on</strong>es. N<strong>on</strong>-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legaleducati<strong>on</strong> (NLE, as opposed to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal law schooleducati<strong>on</strong>) is geared toward making the disadvantagedmore legally self-sufficient by buildingtheir legal capacities. It can take place throughcommunity training sessi<strong>on</strong>s, radio and televisi<strong>on</strong>broadcasts, theatre plays, and printed and audiovisualmaterials and, as discussed below, paralegaldevelopment. A crucial point about theseeducati<strong>on</strong>al ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts is that they must be pitchedat the levels of sophisticati<strong>on</strong> of lay people andtheir particular situati<strong>on</strong>. Effective NLE typicallyborrows from more general internati<strong>on</strong>al developmentpedagogy in that it is interactive and creative.It may feature such techniques as discussi<strong>on</strong>s,games, role-playing and quizzes.Be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e interventi<strong>on</strong>s are c<strong>on</strong>sidered, however, itis useful to investigate what causes the lack ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, why market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces do not provide asoluti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this, and what are the c<strong>on</strong>sequencesof this lack of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the provisi<strong>on</strong> ofjustice services to the poor. In an efficient market<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> justice services, prospective c<strong>on</strong>sumers wouldbe able to evaluate their own legal needs andseek out appropriate providers. Furthermore, c<strong>on</strong>sumerin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about the nature and qualityof the legal services offered would ensure that themarket price <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services reflects the valueof that service to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Not all prospectivec<strong>on</strong>sumers need to be perfectly in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med,because the prices themselves would c<strong>on</strong>veyin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> (cf. Schwartz and Wilde 1979).N<strong>on</strong>etheless, a critical mass of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med potentialc<strong>on</strong>sumers is necessary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the market to allocatelegal services efficiently. If a populati<strong>on</strong> of potentialc<strong>on</strong>sumers lacks sufficient basic in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> what legal services are available, their benefitsand costs they involve, and how to evaluate theirquality, then the market is unlikely to allocatelegal services efficiently even if potential c<strong>on</strong>sumerswould be willing to pay a price that potentialsuppliers would accept.Lack of sufficient in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about legal rightsand entitlements, and about available legal services,is thus problematic <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor themselvesand also causes justice services to be insufficientlyresp<strong>on</strong>sive to the needs of the poor. Butwhy does this lack of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> arise? In mostmarkets, c<strong>on</strong>sumers learn in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about serviceavailability and quality from three sources.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first source of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> is the suppliers,who typically have an incentive to disseminatein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about the services they provide. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>sec<strong>on</strong>d source of c<strong>on</strong>sumer in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistsof other c<strong>on</strong>sumers — either directly of indirectlythrough the price mechanism. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> third sourceof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> is general media coverage. Ifthese three sources of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> are sufficientin most c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets, why might they notbe sufficient to communicate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> aboutrights and legal services to poor communities?Understanding the answer to this questi<strong>on</strong> willhelp re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers design interventi<strong>on</strong>s that are appropriatelytargeted to the underlying problems.We c<strong>on</strong>sider first the questi<strong>on</strong>. Why might legalservice providers not disseminate the relevantin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>? <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are several likely explanati<strong>on</strong>s.First, there may not be providers willing to offerlegal services to a given populati<strong>on</strong> at the pricec<strong>on</strong>sumers would be willing or able to pay. If thatis the reas<strong>on</strong>, then the lack of legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>is a c<strong>on</strong>sequence of some other market failure.This suggests that lack of legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> maysometimes be more symptom than disease. Sec<strong>on</strong>d,general in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about legal rights and20


entitlements is a public good. If expected profitsfrom providing legal services to a poor communityare relatively low and the costs of disseminatingin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> to that community are relatively high,there may be insufficient incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> any <strong>on</strong>ejustice provider to supply in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>yers,courts, or ADR providers may have little reas<strong>on</strong>to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m their possible clients about the rulesthey need to solve their problems. This problemis likely especially acute with respect to legalin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> that is not immediately c<strong>on</strong>nected tothe need to hire a legal professi<strong>on</strong>al. Third, somecountries impose stringent restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> advertising<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services and <strong>on</strong> the unauthorisedpractice of law, and these professi<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>ductrules. Although these restricti<strong>on</strong>s are sometimesdefended as necessary to protect vulnerable c<strong>on</strong>sumersfrom deceptive or misleading in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>,they may also make it difficult <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> service providersto disseminate useful in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> (Rhode2000, Bart<strong>on</strong> 2001).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se observati<strong>on</strong>s suggest that eliminating manyof the other market failures discussed later in thischapter may also redress the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>al problem,as legal service providers will have an incentiveto communicate more about legal entitlementsand how to defend them. Thus, while it isoften supposed that disseminating more in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>about legal rights is the first step in promotingaccess to justice, it may sometimes turn outthat improvements <strong>on</strong> this dimensi<strong>on</strong> follow otherre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms without the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> substantial additi<strong>on</strong>algovernment or d<strong>on</strong>or spending. Also, an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>-disseminati<strong>on</strong>strategy that relies in largemeasure <strong>on</strong> private service providers requires aliberal policy toward the advertising of legal servicesand the solicitati<strong>on</strong> of clients. While manycountries have traditi<strong>on</strong>ally viewed legal advertisingand solicitati<strong>on</strong> as unseemly, overly aggressiveprohibiti<strong>on</strong>s of these activities may stifle theeffective communicati<strong>on</strong> of legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. Inadditi<strong>on</strong> to relying <strong>on</strong> individual service providersto disseminate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, bar associati<strong>on</strong>sand other lawyers’ organisati<strong>on</strong>s are a naturalcandidate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> educating the public about law andlegal services. Because these organisati<strong>on</strong>s representthe legal professi<strong>on</strong> as a whole, they canassist lawyers in overcoming the collective acti<strong>on</strong>problem that reduces the incentives of individuallegal service providers to disseminate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>about legal rights. Bar associati<strong>on</strong>s, however,might have too little incentive to disseminatein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about legal services providers otherthan lawyers, such as paralegals.With respect to the sec<strong>on</strong>d source of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>,other c<strong>on</strong>sumers, when a serviceis c<strong>on</strong>sumed <strong>on</strong>ly rarely within a given populati<strong>on</strong>,then other potential c<strong>on</strong>sumers are unlikelyto be a useful source of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. This suggeststhe possibility of a vicious circle in which adearth of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about legal rights and legalservices leads to limited use of the legal system,and limited use of the legal system perpetuatesthe lack of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about law and legal services.This problem is likely to be especially acutewhen social networks <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sharing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> arerelatively small and insular. To address this problem,re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers should strengthen in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>sharingnetworks that allow transmissi<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>about law and legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. Buildingnetworks of legal service providers, NGOs, andcommunity advocacy groups can go a l<strong>on</strong>g way toincreasing the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal disseminati<strong>on</strong> of legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, the disseminati<strong>on</strong> of legalin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> is likely to be more effective when legalservices are integrated with other social servicesprovided by an umbrella NGO. Unin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>medpotential c<strong>on</strong>sumers are unlikely to seek out alegal service provider if they do not even knowthey have a legal problem. But if they seek out21


some other trusted service provider and discusstheir problem, and that service provider has anadequate knowledge of the legal system, then thepotential legal services c<strong>on</strong>sumer is more likelyto learn that her problem has a legal dimensi<strong>on</strong>and that she can seek some <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of legal redress.This is yet another argument <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘bundling’ legalservices with other social services (ADB 2001a).Third, even when all the above strategies havebeen implemented, there is likely to be a residualneed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> governments or d<strong>on</strong>or-subsidised disseminati<strong>on</strong>of legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, especially generalizedlegal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> that is notimmediately c<strong>on</strong>nected to an <strong>on</strong>going or imminentdispute. For this sort of targeted legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>disseminati<strong>on</strong>, governments and NGOscan make use of the mass media or the Internet.Linguistic barriers (including both language barriersand illiteracy), cultural barriers, and a weakcommunicati<strong>on</strong>s infrastructure (including limitedaccess to radios and televisi<strong>on</strong>s) may limit theeffectiveness of mass media. Different nati<strong>on</strong>almedia also differ in their propensity to devote attenti<strong>on</strong>to legal issues. Experience suggests thatthe best approach to mass legal educati<strong>on</strong> is touse a mix of print media (both newspapers andpamphlets), posters, radio, and televisi<strong>on</strong>, al<strong>on</strong>gwith strategies that integrate legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>into popular entertainment such as comic books,soap operas, popular music, local theatre, andinteractive, participatory activities (ADB 2001a,Abdur-Rahman et al. 2006).However, it should be emphasised that knowledgeusually is not enough. Farmers may learn thatthey are entitled to land. But that knowledge isuseless if government pers<strong>on</strong>nel, the military, acompany or a landlord are powerful enough toignore the law, sometimes by corrupting or intimidatingthe police, the courts or land ministryofficials. Thus, promoting knowledge of the lawis worthwhile, but as a stand-al<strong>on</strong>e strategy itseldom galvanises legal empowerment. And assumingthat knowledge is power can be counterproductiveif it c<strong>on</strong>fines legal empowerment strategiesto simply teaching people their rights.Self Help Interventi<strong>on</strong>s: Forming of Peer GroupsIn the experience of the disadvantaged, it oftenis more correct to say that “organising ispower.” We saw that besides knowledge about thenorms that fit their problems, access to justicealso implies that there is a credible threat of aninterventi<strong>on</strong>. To assert their rights, the disadvantagedoften have to organise around mutual interests.A woman may know that it is illegal <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> herhusband to beat her. But she may <strong>on</strong>ly be able tomake him stop if the women in her communityband together to shame him, pressure otherwiseindifferent police to take acti<strong>on</strong>, persuade malecommunity leaders to intervene or seek the helpof lawyers or NGOs. In this way, they can increasethe incentives <strong>on</strong> their partners or their opp<strong>on</strong>entsto live up to norms.Sometimes community organising (or organisinggroups within a community) can directly targetproblems such as violence against women, lackof land title or property theft. Under other circumstances,where civil society is too weak orentrenched and oppositi<strong>on</strong> too str<strong>on</strong>g, a more indirectapproach may be necessary. Group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>around relatively ‘safe’ development issues such aslivelihood, micro-credit or reproductive health canpave the way <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> more assertive acti<strong>on</strong> down theline, as the groups and their NGO partners gainmore credibility in their communities. Later, <strong>on</strong>cetheir group has established some credibility, andif they so desire, it is possible to focus <strong>on</strong> morerights-oriented work. Women in Bangladesh havethereby benefited from integrati<strong>on</strong> of legal empowermentinto a reproductive health programme22


(Asian Development Bank 2001a). In Nepal, theyhave similarly gained through a multi-faceted empowermentproject that included n<strong>on</strong>-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legaleducati<strong>on</strong> (Thomas and Shrestha 1998).Community-based legal educati<strong>on</strong> seems to havea great empowering potential. Improving legalliteracy may be <strong>on</strong>e goal of legal educati<strong>on</strong>.However, if the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts are additi<strong>on</strong>ally targetedat establishing and maintaining peer supportnetworks, legal educati<strong>on</strong> can be a powerful participatorystrategy that enables people to helpthemselves and to assist others in current andfuture situati<strong>on</strong>s. Peer support networks can beaimed at the <strong>on</strong>going disseminati<strong>on</strong> of generallegal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, provide preventive educati<strong>on</strong>,share knowledge, or teach practical skills. Peergroups can also be tailored to specific legal needsor community groups, such as women wanting tostart a small business. Moreover, peer groups canbe a means to organise people, e.g. to identify,set and promote community priorities, build influence,gain negotiati<strong>on</strong> power, or even developpilot programmes. Paralegals and other legaleducators can accommodate peer networks, e.g.by c<strong>on</strong>jointly developing legal and n<strong>on</strong>-legal strategiesthat match the needs of the community, orhelp building partnerships with the local authorities,and the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system.Broadening the Scope of <strong>Legal</strong>Services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the PoorThis brings us to the next strategy to improveaccess to justice. Like other users of the legalsystem, and even when they become more empoweredto solve problems themselves, the poorwill often need help. Without assistance, theywould likely be incapable of finding the rules thatapply to their situati<strong>on</strong>, and would there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e beunable to induce the ‘other party’ to meet theirrightful demands. Where, then, could the poorfind legal services that fit their problems andtheir resources? Our working group suggests thatef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts be focused <strong>on</strong> following approaches: (1)lower cost delivery models; (2) legal services thatc<strong>on</strong>tribute to empowerment; (3) alternative disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong>; (4) bundling legal services withother services to the poor, and (5) removing artificialc<strong>on</strong>stricti<strong>on</strong>s of supply.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> gist of this strategy is that the poor couldbenefit from an expanded c<strong>on</strong>cepti<strong>on</strong> of what ‘legalservices’ might involve. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are many functi<strong>on</strong>s,bey<strong>on</strong>d legal educati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>allegal representati<strong>on</strong>, which justice services providerslike paralegals can usefully per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seinclude mediating c<strong>on</strong>flicts, organising collectiveacti<strong>on</strong>, and advocating with both traditi<strong>on</strong>aland <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal authorities. This breadth of functi<strong>on</strong>smakes alternative service providers attractive intheir own right, and not merely cheap substitutes<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> lawyers. It is worth highlighting that legalservices have an important role to play in the categoriescovered within the other three chapters ofthis volume; namely, in helping people to securelegal identities, to navigate plural legal systems,and to hold the state accountable. Instead ofviewing legal services narrowly as lawyers providingaccess to courts via <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ensic representati<strong>on</strong>,our working group argues that we should c<strong>on</strong>ceiveof them more broadly, as follows:- That they may include n<strong>on</strong>-lawyers like community-basedparalegals.- That they could also functi<strong>on</strong> in the areas ofadvocacy, mediati<strong>on</strong>, educati<strong>on</strong>, and organising.That their aims as legal service providers includeempowering poor people, increasing the accountabilityof public and private instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and decreasingimpunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> violators of basic rights.23


From an ec<strong>on</strong>omic perspective this strategyaims create an efficient, effective system <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>delivering legal services. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> following analysiswill again be in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med by a transacti<strong>on</strong> costs andmarket failure framework. This approach is unc<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al:most discussi<strong>on</strong> of access to justiceproceeds (1) from the observati<strong>on</strong> that poor peoplehave unmet legal needs, to (2) the assumpti<strong>on</strong>that the best way to remedy this problem isto provide subsidised legal services, to (3) thec<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> that governments and d<strong>on</strong>ors shouldincrease funding <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> various <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of legal aid.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> usual discussi<strong>on</strong> then focuses <strong>on</strong> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mthat legal aid services should take — whetherthey should be delivered by governments orNGOs, whether they should emphasise lawyers,law students, or paralegals, how they should befunded, and so <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>th. Our working group suggeststhat this view of improving access to legal servicesis too narrow. When <strong>on</strong>e defines the problemnot as ‘unmet legal need’, but rather as somespecific failure or distorti<strong>on</strong> in the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legal services, a variety of approaches other thandirect subsidisati<strong>on</strong> emerge, and the appropriatescope <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsidised legal aid services becomesmore refined and more focused.Lower Cost Delivery Models: ParalegalsParalegals and law students are critically importantto improving legal service delivery to poorcommunities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> term ‘paralegal’ may be somewhatmisleading insofar as it suggests an assistantwho per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms ministerial legal tasks. Paralegalsin many developing country programmes arebetter thought of as community activists who not<strong>on</strong>ly have a basic training not in legal principles,but also a familiarity with local community normsand practices and an ability to offer advice andadvocacy services that go bey<strong>on</strong>d narrow legaladvice. Many paralegal programmes have provenefficient and effective in expanding legal assistancein poor communities (McClym<strong>on</strong>t and Golub2000, McQuoid-Mas<strong>on</strong> 2000, and Maru 2006).A particularly notable example is the Timap <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Justice Initiative in Sierra Le<strong>on</strong>e, which hashelped poor individuals deal with problems likecorrupti<strong>on</strong> in government service delivery, domesticviolence and child support, and some criminalmatters (Maru 2006).<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> students are another relatively cost-effectiveway to invest scarce legal aid resources. <strong>Legal</strong>aid clinics staffed by law students or recent lawschool graduates in Russia, Ukraine, South Africa,India, and elsewhere have dem<strong>on</strong>stratedremarkable competence in delivering valuablelegal aid services to poor communities at low cost(Golub 2004, USAID 2002). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, governmentsand d<strong>on</strong>ors who have to allocate a limitedlegal aid budget might do well to place more emphasis<strong>on</strong> supporting the activities of paralegalsand law student clinics.Strengthening the nati<strong>on</strong>al bar associati<strong>on</strong> anddeveloping an effective working relati<strong>on</strong>ship withthe bar is important in developing effective targetedlegal aid programmes, especially when theservices of attorneys are required. Although <strong>on</strong>eto-<strong>on</strong>elawyer-client relati<strong>on</strong>ships would normallynot be af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable by the poor, nor perhaps bygovernments or d<strong>on</strong>ors who might subsidise legalaid, there could be a role here to be played bybar associati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y could help to gather anddisseminate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> in the legal communityabout access to justice issues, and provide useful<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal oversights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y could, moreover,offer political support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> access to justicere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and increased funding <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> necessary legalaid services, help to determine the most worthycandidates <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> targeted legal aid subsidies, andpossibly sp<strong>on</strong>sor c<strong>on</strong>tinuing legal educati<strong>on</strong> programmesc<strong>on</strong>cerned with meeting the legal needsof the poor. It is, of course, possible that some24


ar associati<strong>on</strong>s might be wary of certain approachesto legal services re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m (such as thosethat call <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> increasing competiti<strong>on</strong> in the provisi<strong>on</strong>of legal services or reducing the demand<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services); or, they might be excessivelyenthusiastic about other approaches (those, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, that call <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> large government or d<strong>on</strong>orsubsidies to lawyers who offer legal aid services).Access to justice re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers cannot ignore the bar,even where those structures are weak and disorganised,because the l<strong>on</strong>g-term sustainability ofsubsidised legal aid programmes will also haveto depend <strong>on</strong> the support and collaborati<strong>on</strong> of astr<strong>on</strong>g and motivated lawyers’ associati<strong>on</strong>.<strong>Legal</strong> Services that Empower the ClientsQuality of legal services matters as much as cost,however. In fact, the c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al approach tolegal services envisi<strong>on</strong>s experts providing technicalassistance to needy clients. This approach isnot c<strong>on</strong>cerned with clients’ agency or empowermentoutside the pursuit of redress <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> any givenlegal claim. Some legal services ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts do c<strong>on</strong>sciouslyseek to empower the people with whomthey work. Empowerment techniques includeincorporating educati<strong>on</strong> into every aspect ofservice delivery, working with and strengtheningcommunity organisati<strong>on</strong>s, organising collectiveacti<strong>on</strong> to address justice problems, and engagingin community educati<strong>on</strong> and community dialogue<strong>on</strong> justice issues. Paralegal approaches may beattractive, then, not simply <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> cost advantagesbut also because paralegals may be better positi<strong>on</strong>edto engage in a broader, empowermentorientedmethod of legal service delivery. In theend, however, this is a matter of philosophy andattitude, rather than the professi<strong>on</strong>al status of thelegal service provider.This creates a need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> appropriate training.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing with the poor involves a set of skills thatis quite different from what most law schoolsteach and what most lawyers practice. Mechanisms<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> inculcating these development-orientedskills and perspectives are NGO internships <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>law students and young lawyers and law schoolclinical legal educati<strong>on</strong> programmes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> resultis ‘development lawyering’, as it is sometimescalled, which can involve a willingness to trek outto the remote rural areas or into crowded slums.It can equally involve viewing litigati<strong>on</strong> as a lastresort and administrative advocacy, alternativedispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> and building of the poor legalcapacities as preferred opti<strong>on</strong>s. Such lawyeringfrequently requires skills suitable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> carryingout n<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal educati<strong>on</strong> — interactivetechniques rather than lectures. It involves anawareness of how the law can relate to other developmentfields. This includes viewing the disadvantagedas partners with whom to strategise<strong>on</strong> law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and implementati<strong>on</strong>. Similarly, itincludes listening rather than dictating to clients— the hallmark of any good lawyer, but particularlychallenging in helping impoverished peoplewho usually defer to more educated and affluentindividuals.This type of service may be desirable, but it is notyet clear whether they <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m a sustainable businessmodel and this may be <strong>on</strong>e of the reas<strong>on</strong>sthat there is little sp<strong>on</strong>taneous supply of theseempowering legal services. Suppliers may be hesitantto empower their clients to solve problemsby themselves, because they may fear this leadsto loss of future business.Alternative Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong>Another <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of broadening legal services is toexpand the use of various <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of alternativedispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> (ADR), including small claimscourts, as well as arbitrati<strong>on</strong>, mediati<strong>on</strong>, and c<strong>on</strong>ciliati<strong>on</strong>(Lopez-de-Silanes 2002, Hammergren25


2007). Such mechanisms prove preferable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor because they are more accessible thancourts, af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable, comprehensible and (often)effective. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y can include government administrativetribunals, where paralegals can sometimesprovide representati<strong>on</strong>, such as <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> agrarianre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and labour disputes in the Philippines.Third party arbitrati<strong>on</strong> courts have been set up inmany countries of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer Soviet Uni<strong>on</strong> where,in c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong> with livelihood projects, the partiesselect arbitrators <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> land, agrarian or propertydisputes.This is not to say that ADR is always preferableto, or mutually exclusive with, litigati<strong>on</strong>. It canbe severely hampered by gender biases or otherpower imbalances between disputants (as canthe courts, however). It is often inappropriate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>handling criminal c<strong>on</strong>duct, particularly violentc<strong>on</strong>duct (though n<strong>on</strong>-state systems are oftenstill used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> that purpose). And there are manyc<strong>on</strong>texts, such as with public interest litigati<strong>on</strong> inSouth Africa, where going to court is an effectivelegal implementati<strong>on</strong> strategy.From an ec<strong>on</strong>omic perspective, ADR is most appropriatewhen the primary objective is to resolveindividual disputes over private rights and benefits(Landes and Posner 1979). For those sortsof disputes, the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> substantial public subsidisati<strong>on</strong>of judicial dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> is muchless compelling — though the state may stillneed to supply courts as a backstop to make surethe ADR processes comport with basic principlesof fairness. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers should attempt, when possible,to steer private disputes into appropriate<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of ADR, and to husband scarce judicialresources <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> disputes that involve public goods(including the articulati<strong>on</strong> of norms and principles)and fundamental public values.In additi<strong>on</strong> to the arbitrati<strong>on</strong>, mediati<strong>on</strong>, and c<strong>on</strong>ciliati<strong>on</strong>programmes traditi<strong>on</strong>ally associated withADR, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers might also address the demand<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> judicial services by encouraging or requiringthe resoluti<strong>on</strong> of more disputes (at least in thefirst instance) in the administrative bureaucracyrather than the courts. For example, the claimsof injured workers could be resolved by workers’compensati<strong>on</strong> boards rather than in lawsuitsagainst employers. C<strong>on</strong>sumer issues could bebrought be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e easy accessible, low-cost c<strong>on</strong>sumercommittees. A similar strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> reducingdemand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> expensive judicial services is to adoptre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the resoluti<strong>on</strong> of certaintypes of disputes according to customary law orother traditi<strong>on</strong>al practices of the n<strong>on</strong>-state sector.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se approaches raise a host of additi<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>cerns related to the equity and efficiency ofthe bureaucratic justice system and the n<strong>on</strong>-statejustice system, which subsequent secti<strong>on</strong>s of thischapter will discuss in more detail. For purposesof the present discussi<strong>on</strong>, bureaucratic and customarydispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered asspecial types of ADR.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> design of just and effective ADR systemsis itself an enormous topic. It is also a subjectwhere it is difficult to make general recommendati<strong>on</strong>s,because the optimal design of ADR systemsdepends very much <strong>on</strong> the unique circumstancesof each country. Three c<strong>on</strong>cerns aboutADR programmes are especially prominent. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>first is that these programmes are often biasedin favour of powerful interests and lack adequatesafeguards to protect less sophisticated parties(UNDP 2005).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d c<strong>on</strong>cern is that ADR programmestend to become increasingly ‘proceduralised’over time — that is, they begin to look more likequasi-courts, and they lose the cost and speedadvantages that justified their creati<strong>on</strong> in the firstplace. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> third c<strong>on</strong>cern has to do with the final-26


ity of ADR decisi<strong>on</strong>s. If it is too easy to challengean ADR ruling in court, then parties do not have asufficient incentive to take ADR seriously (Shavell1995). On the other hand, the harder it is to c<strong>on</strong>testADR decisi<strong>on</strong>s, the greater the c<strong>on</strong>cern thatimportant individual rights and entitlements arebeing decided outside of the judicial system byn<strong>on</strong>-state actors.While all of these problems are serious and legitimatec<strong>on</strong>cerns, a number of countries have hadc<strong>on</strong>siderable success crafting ADR programmesthat reduce the burden <strong>on</strong> the judicial systemand increase access at a relatively low cost. InBangladesh, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, local mediati<strong>on</strong> councilsresolve 60 -70 percent of local disputes (US-AID 2002). In Argentina, the Ministry of Justiceand USAID supported the creati<strong>on</strong> of legal servicecentres in Buenos Aires to provide mediati<strong>on</strong>services, and these centres appear to have beeneffective (USAID 2002). Again, while the designof appropriate ADR programmes is challengingand c<strong>on</strong>text-dependent, most available evidenceindicates that developing cost-effective ADR programmesis an important though imperfect meansof providing an alternative to using an overcrowdedcourt system.Bundling with Other Services<strong>Legal</strong> aid programmes are most effective whenthey are bundled with other social services ratherthan offered as stand-al<strong>on</strong>e programmes. Forexample, the South African <strong>Legal</strong> Aid Board,which experimented with a variety of models <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>providing civil legal aid, found that the most effectivemodel is a ‘justice centre’ model — a ‘<strong>on</strong>estop legal shop’ that provides comprehensivelegal services through a combinati<strong>on</strong> of lawyers,advocates, paralegals, and administrative staff(MacQuoid-Mas<strong>on</strong> 2000). Similarly, many LatinAmerican countries have had success with ‘Casasde Justicia’ (Houses of Justice) that provide assistancewith both legal and n<strong>on</strong>-legal aspectsof comm<strong>on</strong> problems, such as child support andcustody issues, property disputes, domestic violence,and administrative matters (USAID 2002).This model may be more effective than state subsidisati<strong>on</strong>of private lawyers and advocates whoprovide legal services to the poor.Arelated point is that internati<strong>on</strong>al d<strong>on</strong>orshave had more success funding local NGOsthat provide a variety of services, including legalservices, than in funding NGOs that provideexclusively legal services. More encompassingorganisati<strong>on</strong>s tend to be more effective in reachingthe target populati<strong>on</strong>, and they also tend to bemore sustainable in the l<strong>on</strong>g term (ADB 2001a).Thus, adding legal services capacity to existingcommunity-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s is a more promisingstrategy than supporting or establishing neworganisati<strong>on</strong>s that focus exclusively <strong>on</strong> providinglegal aid. One possible ‘bundling’ strategy thatholds particular promise is the integrati<strong>on</strong> of legalaid services with microfinance instituti<strong>on</strong>s (MFIs).MFIs have regular access to poor communities anda group-based service delivery model well-suited tolegal aid services, especially when collective acti<strong>on</strong>is necessary. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers have already begun to experimentwith incorporating health and educati<strong>on</strong>services within existing MFIs, and early indicati<strong>on</strong>ssuggest this integrati<strong>on</strong> has been effective (Dun<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d2002). Adding legal aid services seems like areas<strong>on</strong>able next stepMany of the generic and actual examples citedin this paper reflect how legal implementati<strong>on</strong>can build <strong>on</strong> or integrate with other developmentactivities and fields. In fact, legal empowermentoften is most effective when this takes place.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> integrati<strong>on</strong> with community organising andgroup <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> represents this phenomen<strong>on</strong>.Another example is the use of the media, which27


can play an important role in mobilising the poorto assert their rights or the public to support theiradvocacy. In a more substantive vein, the urbanpoor and tenant farmers who receive land titlesmay need multi-faceted assistance to make bestuse of their new property. This can include advice<strong>on</strong> and availability of credit programmes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer and agricultural technologies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the latter.Removing C<strong>on</strong>stricti<strong>on</strong>s of the Supply of <strong>Legal</strong>Services to the PoorAnother reas<strong>on</strong> why poor individuals may not haveadequate access to legal services is the artificialc<strong>on</strong>stricti<strong>on</strong> of the supply of legal service providers.In an efficient market, if potential c<strong>on</strong>sumersare willing to pay more than it would cost a potentialsupplier to provide a service, the providershould enter the market to provide the service.Collectively, this dynamic should drive the priceof the service down to an efficient level. However,if barriers to entry prevent potential suppliersfrom entering the market, the market price willbe artificially high and certain c<strong>on</strong>sumers willnot be able to acquire services they would liketo purchase. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> excluded c<strong>on</strong>sumers are oftenthe poor, since they are less able to pay a highermarket price.Many observers believe that this sort of marketfailure is comm<strong>on</strong> — perhaps pervasive — in themarket <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are two primaryreas<strong>on</strong>s why the supply of legal service providersmight be artificially c<strong>on</strong>stricted. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first has todo with the nature of legal educati<strong>on</strong>, and thesec<strong>on</strong>d has to do with the regulati<strong>on</strong> of the legalprofessi<strong>on</strong>.With respect to educati<strong>on</strong>, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal systemin many countries is the province of the elite,and this legal elitism extends to the way in whichlawyers are trained. Many law schools preparetheir students to practice the sort of law that ismost relevant to the affluent or to the internati<strong>on</strong>albusiness community, and the populati<strong>on</strong> of lawstudents is often drawn disproporti<strong>on</strong>ately fromthe more well-to-do segment of society. On top ofthis, in many countries the number of slots at lawschools is very limited: often there are <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>eor two major public law schools with a limitednumber of spaces, and it is difficult <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> privatelaw schools to enter the market.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> end result is a supply problem: Developingcountry law schools train few lawyersoverall; the lawyers that are trained are disproporti<strong>on</strong>atelyinterested in the legal problems ofthe elite; and those lawyers who might c<strong>on</strong>siderfocusing <strong>on</strong> the legal problems of the poor facesubstantial entry barriers because they have notreceived much early training in the relevant fieldsand skills (NCLEP Ethiopia 2007). Even if representati<strong>on</strong>of poor clients could prove financiallyor pers<strong>on</strong>ally rewarding <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> larger numbers of potentiallawyers, distorti<strong>on</strong>s in the legal educati<strong>on</strong>system may entrench distorti<strong>on</strong>s in the supply ofsuch lawyers relative to what <strong>on</strong>e would observein a hypothetical efficient market.One step that might redress this problem is tomake it easier to enter the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> providinglegal educati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example by relaxing accreditati<strong>on</strong>requirements or encouraging distancelearning. Elite lawyers might sneer at ‘nightschool’ or ‘trade school’ lawyers, but expandingthe opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal educati<strong>on</strong> willhelp increase the supply of lawyers, especiallylawyers who come from n<strong>on</strong>-elite backgrounds.Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, it may be advisable to create andfund more training programmes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> paralegalsor other n<strong>on</strong>-lawyer service providers (McLym<strong>on</strong>tand Golub 2000), as well as training programmes<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> practicing lawyers who want to move intopractice areas that emphasise the provisi<strong>on</strong> oflegal services to poor or otherwise disadvantaged28


clients. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> organised bar or other associati<strong>on</strong>s oflegal professi<strong>on</strong>als may be especially helpful inpursuing these goals, especially in the c<strong>on</strong>test ofc<strong>on</strong>tinuing legal educati<strong>on</strong>.Of course, <strong>on</strong>e must guard against the dangersof ‘diploma mills’ that give students alaw degree but not any real skills or training, especiallywhen these fly-by-night operati<strong>on</strong>s exploitless educated prospective students. This dangershould not be exaggerated, especially when comparedwith the significant costs associated withoverly limited opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal educati<strong>on</strong>.Nevertheless, in some developing countries, thepoor may suffer as much from an ‘oversupply’of poorly-trained, dish<strong>on</strong>est ‘lawyers’ as they dofrom an under-supply of competent lawyers interestedin representing poor clients. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> soluti<strong>on</strong>to the quality c<strong>on</strong>trol problem, however, cannotbe sharp restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> access to legal educati<strong>on</strong>.Rather, it must be a combinati<strong>on</strong> of sensibleregulati<strong>on</strong>, market competiti<strong>on</strong>, and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>disseminati<strong>on</strong>.In additi<strong>on</strong> to expanding opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legaleducati<strong>on</strong> and training, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the nature oflegal educati<strong>on</strong> at the elite law schools couldmake it easier <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> young lawyers to pursue careersthat include a substantial amount of public servicework or compensated representati<strong>on</strong> of poorclients. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no <strong>on</strong>e right way to do this, anddifferent law schools will necessarily take differentapproaches to curricular re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. With that caveat,possible re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms might include expanding courseofferings <strong>on</strong> subjects of particular relevance topoor clients (such as landlord-tenant law, labourlaw, land law, natural resources law, customarylaw, mass torts, and criminal defence); providingmore opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> clinical legal educati<strong>on</strong>;and using incentives or requirements to encouragelaw students to spend a period of time aftergraduati<strong>on</strong> doing public interest work or providinglegal aid. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, elite law schools shouldexplore ways to increase enrolment of studentsfrom disadvantaged backgrounds, and to providespecial classes to such students so that they cancompete with their classmates from elite backgrounds(Men<strong>on</strong> 2007). While there is no guaranteethat students from disadvantaged backgroundswill end up providing legal services to the poor,they are probably more likely to do so as a statisticalmatter, and they may also serve as role models<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> other members of their communities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> risk of an approach that emphasises drawingmore talented young people — especiallytalented young people from disadvantaged backgrounds— into the legal professi<strong>on</strong> is that theirtalents might be better deployed in some otherfield (Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny 1991). Manywho think and write about legal educati<strong>on</strong> andlegal aid have an un<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tunate tendency to neglectthe opportunity costs associated with a greaterallocati<strong>on</strong> of talent to the legal sector. Nevertheless,in most developing countries the supply oflegal service providers in poor communities is soc<strong>on</strong>stricted, and existing law school training isso distorted in the directi<strong>on</strong> of preparing younglawyers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> elite practice, that the benefits of expandingthe opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal educati<strong>on</strong> arelikely to exceed whatever costs arise from divertingsome number of talented youths from alternativecareers in business, medicine, science,public service, or some other calling.Distorti<strong>on</strong> in the legal educati<strong>on</strong> system is <strong>on</strong>esource of the supply problem in the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalservices. Another potential problem may arisewhen countries adopt stringent ‘unauthorisedpractice of law’ rules — that is, when countriesmandate that certain legal services can <strong>on</strong>ly beoffered by a certain legal professi<strong>on</strong>als, such aslicensed attorneys, barristers, or notaries. Whilethese restricti<strong>on</strong>s may arise from the purest of29


motives — such as the desire to maintain minimumquality standards and to protect c<strong>on</strong>sumersfrom exploitati<strong>on</strong> — they often have the effectof c<strong>on</strong>ferring a m<strong>on</strong>opoly <strong>on</strong> a particular set oflegal service providers. This drives up the priceof legal services to the disadvantage of c<strong>on</strong>sumersin general and poor c<strong>on</strong>sumers in particular(Rhode 2009, 2004, Spaulding 2004). Thisphenomen<strong>on</strong> has led to calls in some quarters <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>complete eliminati<strong>on</strong> of prohibiti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the unauthorisedpractice of law, and in other quarters <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>more modest changes that would allow paralegalsand lay people to per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m a larger proporti<strong>on</strong> ofthe activities that are currently restricted to legalprofessi<strong>on</strong>als (Cantrell 2004, Kritzer 1997,Rhode 2004, NCLEP Philippines 2007).Though some bar associati<strong>on</strong>s have shown an appreciati<strong>on</strong>of the problem and indicated a desireto work with re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers to liberalise the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legal services, other legal professi<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>shave fiercely opposed any re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that mightthreaten their m<strong>on</strong>opoly <strong>on</strong> legal services (Hammergren2007, Messick 1999). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> argumentsagainst loosening restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> who can providelegal services typically emphasise the need to protectc<strong>on</strong>sumers from incompetent or unscrupulousservice providers. Of course, many service marketsfuncti<strong>on</strong> effectively without strict ex ante licensingschemes and entry barriers, so the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thissort of regulati<strong>on</strong> in the legal services c<strong>on</strong>text ishardly self-evident. Moreover, there is a small butgrowing body of empirical research — most of it,admittedly, c<strong>on</strong>ducted in rich countries — thatindicates n<strong>on</strong>-lawyers (especially paralegals) andlay people can per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m a variety of ‘legal’ servicesas effectively as lawyers, and that marketmechanisms and less intrusive regulati<strong>on</strong> can beeffective in protecting c<strong>on</strong>sumers from exploitati<strong>on</strong>(Cantrell 2004, Kritzer 1997, Domberger andSherr 1989). This evidence, though suggestiverather than c<strong>on</strong>clusive, indicates that liberalisati<strong>on</strong>of the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services — in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ofweakening restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> who can provide particularlegal services — is likely to improve access tojustice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor substantially, while imposingrelatively few costs <strong>on</strong> society so l<strong>on</strong>g as alternativequality-c<strong>on</strong>trol instituti<strong>on</strong>s are in place.A major attracti<strong>on</strong> of a re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategy that emphasisesthe liberalisati<strong>on</strong> of the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal servicesis that, compared to many other legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mstrategies, liberalisati<strong>on</strong> may require fewer governmentor d<strong>on</strong>or expenditures, at least in the medium-to l<strong>on</strong>g-term. Instead of compensating <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> amarket distorti<strong>on</strong> through c<strong>on</strong>tinuous payments tothe individuals, the liberalisati<strong>on</strong> strategy focuses<strong>on</strong> curing a market distorti<strong>on</strong> through a change inthe regulatory scheme. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> major obstacle to theliberalisati<strong>on</strong> strategy, however, is likely to be political:As noted above, many (though not all) associati<strong>on</strong>sof legal professi<strong>on</strong>als str<strong>on</strong>gly oppose thissort of liberalisati<strong>on</strong>. Organised legal professi<strong>on</strong>alsare indispensable partners in achieving the objectivesof expanding access to justice and promotinglegal empowerment (Grajzl and Murrell 2006), andit would be a serious mistake to alienate the barby adopting an overly c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong>al posture withrespect to the liberalisati<strong>on</strong> in the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalservices. Though the appropriate implementati<strong>on</strong>strategy will depend <strong>on</strong> the specific circumstancesof each individual case, as a rule of thumb it isprobably advisable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers to work with thebar to find points of agreement and opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> collaborati<strong>on</strong>; to begin the process of liberalisingthe legal services market with those legalservices where the most powerful lawyers andlawyers’ associati<strong>on</strong>s are least threatened; and toemphasise <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of liberalisati<strong>on</strong> that increase theparticipati<strong>on</strong> of n<strong>on</strong>-lawyers in c<strong>on</strong>texts were fewlawyers currently offer services.For example, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers could support special ex-30


cepti<strong>on</strong>s to ‘unauthorised practice’ restricti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>paralegals that want to offer legal services in poorrural communities that are not currently servedby many lawyers. Or, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers could encouragearrangements where n<strong>on</strong>-lawyers provide servicesunder the nominal supervisi<strong>on</strong> of a licensed legalprofessi<strong>on</strong>al (cf. Maru 2006). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se gradual firststeps may build political support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> broader liberalisati<strong>on</strong>of the legal services market while atthe same time reassuring the legal establishmentthat doing so will not threaten their livelihoodor undermine the reputati<strong>on</strong> and integrity of theprofessi<strong>on</strong>. A further advantage to this gradualistapproach is that it allows <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> regular feedbackand adjustments to make sure that c<strong>on</strong>sumer interestsare adequately protected in the liberalisedmarket. A badly designed and overly aggressiveliberalisati<strong>on</strong> strategy is likely to backfire if largenumbers of c<strong>on</strong>sumers find themselves victimisedby dish<strong>on</strong>est or incompetent service providers.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fundamental point here is that the legal servicesmarket will not operate efficiently <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the benefitof the poor if the supply of individuals who cansupply legal services to poor people is artificiallyc<strong>on</strong>stricted by the nature of the legal educati<strong>on</strong>system or by a regulatory regime that restrictsentry excessively. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers shouldadopt measures, appropriate to the particular circumstances,to eliminate both distorti<strong>on</strong>s in thesystem of legal educati<strong>on</strong> and restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> themarket <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services, when these distorti<strong>on</strong>sand restricti<strong>on</strong>s artificially restrict the supply oflegal service providers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor communities.Financing of Claims: <strong>Legal</strong> Insurance andTargeted <strong>Legal</strong> Aid<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> costs of justice services are likely to remainc<strong>on</strong>siderable, even if the broadening suggested inthe preceding paragraphs would take place. Butindividuals do not need expensive legal servicesfrequently. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se events are likely to occur <strong>on</strong>ceor a few times in their lifetime. Even then thecosts can be limited, unless it is necessary totake the issue up to a court <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> litigati<strong>on</strong> and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement.So it is interesting to c<strong>on</strong>sider whetherthe costs of litigati<strong>on</strong> can be insured by privateor public arrangements, or whether governmentsshould invest in subsidising these services.• Insofar as legal services c<strong>on</strong>fer private benefits<strong>on</strong> individuals, <strong>on</strong>e might expect thatthese services would be efficiently suppliedin well-structured private markets. If peoplewould benefit from hiring a lawyer to helpwith a problem or dispute, they will hire <strong>on</strong>e.If the cost of securing legal representati<strong>on</strong>exceeds the expected value of the services,then it would be inefficient to hire a lawyer.But in the real world, serious market failurescomplicate this facile characterisati<strong>on</strong> of thelegal services market. One set of problems,discussed below, is that the costs of pursuinga legal claim may deter even those with positiveexpected value claims from retaining thenecessary legal services. Even if we put thatproblem aside, we would still have to c<strong>on</strong>sidertwo other market failures that can leave litigantswho ought to retain a lawyer unable todo so: First, private mechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> providingoptimal insurance against legal risks are oftenunavailable or inadequate.• Sec<strong>on</strong>d, many poor people lack access to awell-functi<strong>on</strong>ing private market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> financingthe pursuit of their legal claims. Both of theseproblems share a comm<strong>on</strong> root: poor peoplehave limited assets, but litigati<strong>on</strong> typicallyrequires a relatively large up-fr<strong>on</strong>t transfer ofresources to a legal services provider.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> inadequate insurance problem arises primarilyin cases where a poor individual is the target31


of some legal acti<strong>on</strong> brought by the governmentor another party. For example, a poor pers<strong>on</strong>may suddenly find herself the target of an evicti<strong>on</strong>proceeding, a private lawsuit, or — mostterrifying of all — a criminal prosecuti<strong>on</strong>. Whenthis sort of disaster occurs, the individual maysuddenly find herself in need of expensive legalservices, but she may not have sufficient assets<strong>on</strong> hand to pay these costs herself. One mightreas<strong>on</strong>ably suppose that the private value to thepotential target of having access to such servicesin case of a legal emergency exceeds the probability-discountedcost to potential providers ofpromising to make such services available. Inother c<strong>on</strong>texts where this is the case, privatefirst-party insurance markets emerge: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> potentiallyneedy individual pays some regular fee tothe insurer, and in the event of emergency theinsurer pays the majority of the cost of providingthe emergency service. But although efficientprivate insurance markets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services havedeveloped in some parts of Europe (Killian 2003,Regan 2003), they are generally rare elsewhere inthe world. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> lack of effective insurance againstlegal risk burdens the poor much more than theaffluent, because the affluent are better able toself-insure — <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, by having large ‘rainyday funds’ available to cover un<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eseen emergencyexpenditures.One reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dearth of effective private legalinsurance arrangements may be the genericproblem that very poor individuals devote all theirassets to short-term subsistence; they would notbe willing or able to buy legal insurance even if itwere available. Insofar as that is the main cause,the most obvious soluti<strong>on</strong> is straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>wardredistributi<strong>on</strong> of wealth rather than any re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mtargeted at legal services specifically. Anotherreas<strong>on</strong> may be that poor people lack sufficientaccess to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about the benefits of legalinsurance. This c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> is a variant <strong>on</strong> thegeneral c<strong>on</strong>cern about the lack of adequate legalin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, c<strong>on</strong>sidered in a later secti<strong>on</strong>.Other reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a failure in the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalinsurance involve problems with insurance marketsgenerally. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first problem is ‘moral hazard’:those with insurance are less likely to take care toavoid taking acti<strong>on</strong>s that are likely to trigger theneed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> insurance coverage. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d problemis ‘adverse selecti<strong>on</strong>’: those at greater risk aremore likely to purchase insurance, which leadsto a vicious cycle in which price increases deterpurchases by relatively lower-risk individuals, andthe increasing c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> of high-risk individualsin the insurance pool drives the price upfurther (Bolt<strong>on</strong> and Dewatrip<strong>on</strong>t 2005). In otherprivate insurance markets, providers and regulatorstry to deal with the moral hazard and adverseselecti<strong>on</strong> problems through devices like deductiblesand co-payments, price discriminati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>the basis of risk factors, and mandatory groupinsurance plans. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se mechanisms may not beadequate to address the problem in the c<strong>on</strong>text oflegal insurance, however. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> result, then, is thatmany people of modest means may not be ableto purchase private insurance against legal risks,even if they are willing and able to do so.One straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward soluti<strong>on</strong> to pervasive failuresin the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal insurance is <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the stateor the internati<strong>on</strong>al d<strong>on</strong>or community to step in toprovide universal insurance against certain typesof legal risks. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most obvious and widespread<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of government-administered legal insuranceis the provisi<strong>on</strong> of public defenders <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigentcriminal defendants. Governments and NGOs thatoffer free or subsidised legal assistance to individualsfighting evicti<strong>on</strong>, defending against civillawsuits, or c<strong>on</strong>testing fines levied by governmentagencies are also essentially providing subsidisedlegal insurance.32


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> government or d<strong>on</strong>or-funded legalinsurance is powerful in the presence of the marketfailures described above, but it is important torecognise that such insurance is very expensive.It also involves significant redistributi<strong>on</strong> of socialresources — not <strong>on</strong>ly from the well-off to thepoor, but am<strong>on</strong>g different sub-groups of the poor.Subsidised legal insurance does nothing to mitigatethe moral hazard problem, and it may erodeindividual’s incentives to take precauti<strong>on</strong>s to avoidbeing subject to legal acti<strong>on</strong>. Subsidised insurancealso reduces the incentives of marginally indigentindividuals to self-insure even when they coulddo so (cf. Hoffman, Rubin and Shepherd 2005).Moreover, although there is no adverse selecti<strong>on</strong>problem under a universal insurance scheme— because opting out is impossible — the schemetransfers resources from people who rarely makeuse of emergency legal services to those who usethese services more frequently. Often this resourcetransfer takes the near-invisible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of the opportunitycosts of the resources spent <strong>on</strong> emergencylegal services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> high-risk individuals and groups.Those resources might otherwise have been spent<strong>on</strong> other legal or n<strong>on</strong>-legal services that would benefitdifferent populati<strong>on</strong>s of poor individuals.This is not to say that state or d<strong>on</strong>or provisi<strong>on</strong>of emergency legal insurance is a bad idea.Indeed, in some cases — such as the provisi<strong>on</strong>of competent criminal defence counsel free ofcharge to indigent defendants — state-fundedlegal insurance may be a moral and legal obligati<strong>on</strong>.But because the operati<strong>on</strong> of a universallegal insurance scheme is so costly, it is worthc<strong>on</strong>sidering other techniques that re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mersmight employ to redress the failures in the market<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> emergency legal insurance. One such approachis to expand the use of local communitybasedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s that allow individuals to pooltheir risk. For example, labour uni<strong>on</strong>s can — andoften do — provide legal services <strong>on</strong> behalf oftheir members, especially to c<strong>on</strong>test terminati<strong>on</strong>decisi<strong>on</strong>s and adverse employment c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.Tenants’ associati<strong>on</strong>s can provide emergencylegal assistance to c<strong>on</strong>test evicti<strong>on</strong>s; similarly,while landlords’ associati<strong>on</strong>s can offer emergencylegal assistance to take acti<strong>on</strong> against unruly ordestructive tenants. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> advantage of relying <strong>on</strong>small community-based representative groups toprovide emergency legal insurance is that thesegroups may be better able to m<strong>on</strong>itor and policetheir members and to apporti<strong>on</strong> insurance costsin rough proporti<strong>on</strong> to risk.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> financing problem typically involves poorindividuals who have some legal claim — eithera positive legal entitlement or an injury to a legallyprotected interest — that has a positivem<strong>on</strong>etisable value that is greater than the cost ofthe legal services necessary to pursue the claim.In an efficient market, because this claim has apositive net expected value, the individual shouldbe able to retain representati<strong>on</strong> and receive anaward (perhaps through litigati<strong>on</strong>, but more likelyin a settlement) that exceeds the cost of the legalservices. But in many cases poor individuals d<strong>on</strong>ot have the assets <strong>on</strong>-hand to pay the up-fr<strong>on</strong>tfees necessary to retain legal services in theprivate market (Yeazell 2006). Moreover, theirdisputes usually unfold with other poor peopleas defendants, and are mostly about divisi<strong>on</strong> ofproperty rather than damages. It is unlikely thatthere is a ‘deep pocket’ around that can be thetarget of a claim. For these reas<strong>on</strong>s, the soluti<strong>on</strong>that their claim is financed by others — by theirlawyer <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance — is usually not available.That being said, there may be situati<strong>on</strong>s wherefinancing of claims is an opti<strong>on</strong>, such as in thecase of pers<strong>on</strong>al injury arising from road trafficaccidents, and this will increasingly be the caseat higher stages of development. To that end gov-33


ernments may c<strong>on</strong>sider to remove artificial barriersto the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> financing of claims, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instanceby changing the rules against c<strong>on</strong>tingencyfee arrangements (Kritzer 2004, Yeazell 2006),although this may prove to be a c<strong>on</strong>troversial issue.Another alternative, which combines elements ofthe c<strong>on</strong>tingency fee system with a more traditi<strong>on</strong>alcivil legal aid system, is the ‘c<strong>on</strong>tingency legal aidfund’ (CLAF) (Capper 2003). In a CLAF system,the government establishes a fund to subsidiselitigati<strong>on</strong> by indigent civil plaintiffs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>yers whorepresent such plaintiffs are reimbursed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a porti<strong>on</strong>of their costs if they lose. If they win, <strong>on</strong> theother hand, they are required to c<strong>on</strong>tribute a porti<strong>on</strong>of the damage award to replenish the fund.A CLAF system would place more burden <strong>on</strong> thepublic treasury than a system that relied <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tingencyfees, but it would be less expensive thana traditi<strong>on</strong>al civil legal aid system. Similarly, whilea CLAF system would have less powerful incentiveeffects than a c<strong>on</strong>tingency fee system: cases witha low probability of winning look more attractive,and cases with a high probability of winning lookless attractive, under a CLAF system as comparedto a c<strong>on</strong>tingency fee system. Whether that is agood thing or a bad thing depends <strong>on</strong> the socialvalue we attach to expanding the opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>individuals with facially weak claims to have accessto a lawyer. CLAF may also be an attractive‘middle way’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> countries that have traditi<strong>on</strong>allyrejected c<strong>on</strong>tingency fees, but are interested inexperimenting with market- or incentive-basedalternatives to traditi<strong>on</strong>al civil legal aid. It is alsopossible to use the same basic approach suggestedabove <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> emergency legal insurance:greater reliance <strong>on</strong> relatively small, communitybasedrepresentative organisati<strong>on</strong>s. In additi<strong>on</strong> toproviding support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> members who are facing alegal emergency, these organisati<strong>on</strong>s could alsoprovide financial support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> members who need tohire a legal professi<strong>on</strong>al to pursue a legal claim <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>damages against some other party; the claimant,if victorious, could then pay back the organisati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fr<strong>on</strong>ting the m<strong>on</strong>ey. Alternatively organisati<strong>on</strong>slarge enough to retain their own legal servicescould ‘loan’ their legal representatives to membersin need without charge.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> preceding discussi<strong>on</strong> has focused primarily<strong>on</strong> cases in which an individual’sability to access legal services c<strong>on</strong>fers benefitsprimarily <strong>on</strong> that individual. However, the privatebenefits that an individual may derive from effectiveaccess to the legal system may not alwaysbe equal to the social interest in providing suchaccess (Shavell 1997). In some cases, the socialresources — in terms of both time and m<strong>on</strong>ey— that result from an individual’s pursuit of alegal claim may be very high, even though thecosts to the individual are relatively low. In thosecases, individuals will have an incentive to ‘overc<strong>on</strong>sume’legal and judicial resources. In othercases, and that is far more likely to be a problemin relati<strong>on</strong> to the rights of the poor, individualpursuit of legal claims may c<strong>on</strong>fer more generalbenefits <strong>on</strong> a larger class of people, or <strong>on</strong> societygenerally. In those cases, individuals may havetoo little incentive to press their legal claims.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are three primary reas<strong>on</strong>s why this mightoccur.First, each individual legal claim brought by aninjured victim against an injurer c<strong>on</strong>tributes to thegeneral deterrence of unlawful c<strong>on</strong>duct. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> individualclaimant, however, does not internalie thefull value of this deterrence benefit (Shavell 1997).Sec<strong>on</strong>d, where an individual seeks a remedy thatinvolves the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of an instituti<strong>on</strong> or the eliminati<strong>on</strong>of a harmful unlawful practice, that remedy,like general deterrence, will typically benefit34


a much larger class of people. As a result, eachindividual’s incentive to pursue that systemicrelief may be too small.Third, each individual who pursues a legal claimmay influence the development of the underlyingsubstantive law. Comparative studies have foundthat this is true even in countries where, as a matterof official legal ideology, judges merely applypre-existing law to new disputes (MacCormick andSummers 1991, 1997). Even though an individuallitigant internalises some of the benefit of a favourablechange in the law, she typically will notinternalise the full social benefits of such changes.Thus, individuals have insufficiently str<strong>on</strong>g incentivesto press <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> beneficial legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m (Landesand Posner 1979). Furthermore, litigants whohave <strong>on</strong>ly occasi<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>tact with the legal systemwill be at a disadvantage to entities that are‘repeat players’, because the latter will generallyhave a str<strong>on</strong>ger incentive to influence the developmentof the law. This may put poor individuals ata systematic disadvantage relative to entrenchedinstituti<strong>on</strong>s and elites (Galanter 1974).For these and other reas<strong>on</strong>s, the pursuit of legalclaims — and the investment in capable legalservice providers to advance these claims — maybenefit many besides those directly involved.Where disputes have such ‘public goods’ characteristics,individual demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services willbe too low from a social perspective. In thesesituati<strong>on</strong>s, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that provide an incentive tosecure legal services specifically (as opposed toef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to redistribute income generally) may beappropriate.One approach to redressing this type of marketfailure would be <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> governments, NGOs, or internati<strong>on</strong>ald<strong>on</strong>ors to provide targeted legal assistancein cases where the individual pursuit of alegal claim is most likely to c<strong>on</strong>fer a public goodas well as a private benefit (Shavell 1997). Asec<strong>on</strong>d approach to addressing this sort of marketfailure would be to empower local communityadvocacy groups and other representative civilsociety organisati<strong>on</strong>s (including, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example,public interest advocacy groups, labour uni<strong>on</strong>s,renters’ or landlords’ associati<strong>on</strong>s, and coaliti<strong>on</strong>sof small business interests) to pursue legalclaims <strong>on</strong> behalf of their members. While theseorganisati<strong>on</strong>s may not be perfect representativesof collective or public interests, they may have astr<strong>on</strong>ger incentive to pursue legal relief that hasbroad public benefits than does any <strong>on</strong>e individual.An established community organisati<strong>on</strong> isalso more likely to be a repeat player in the legalsystem, which means that it typically will have astr<strong>on</strong>ger incentive to pursue a l<strong>on</strong>g-term strategyof legal change. Furthermore, community-basedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, while hardly perfect, are likelyto have better judgment than nati<strong>on</strong>al governments,internati<strong>on</strong>al d<strong>on</strong>ors, or other NGOs aboutwhat allocati<strong>on</strong> of scarce legal aid resources willachieve the greatest collective benefit.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se observati<strong>on</strong>s suggest three approachesto strengthening the role of local civil societyorganisati<strong>on</strong>s. First, it is important to create aninstituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment in which such groupsare relatively easy to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and sustain (NCLEPPhilippines 2007). Sec<strong>on</strong>d, it may often be awise to empower organisati<strong>on</strong>s to pursue legalremedies <strong>on</strong> behalf of their members orthe general public. Relaxing rules <strong>on</strong> who canbring a suit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, by liberalising standingrequirements and expanding the availabilityof representative acti<strong>on</strong>s, two re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that theIndian Supreme Court has pi<strong>on</strong>eered, may enablecommunity organisati<strong>on</strong>s to pursue publicinterest litigati<strong>on</strong> even when no individual wouldhave a sufficient incentive to do so (Dembowski2000). Third, because local community organi-35


sati<strong>on</strong>s may make better decisi<strong>on</strong>s about how totarget scarce legal aid resources, it is often advisable<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> governments and internati<strong>on</strong>al d<strong>on</strong>orsto provide funding to these local organisati<strong>on</strong>sand allow them to decide how to allocate theseresources. That suggesti<strong>on</strong> must be tempered,however, with the recogniti<strong>on</strong> that corrupti<strong>on</strong>and abuse by these local organisati<strong>on</strong>s may beserious c<strong>on</strong>cerns. Thus, effective m<strong>on</strong>itoring isessential. Finally, and more c<strong>on</strong>troversially, theincentives of claimants or legal service providersto pursue claims that serve the public good maybe strengthened through the use of special damageawards and fee-shifting arrangements.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> preceding discussi<strong>on</strong> leads to the followinggeneral recommendati<strong>on</strong>s:• First, in the c<strong>on</strong>text of legal entitlements witha high private value, governments and d<strong>on</strong>orsshould target their subsidies at those caseswhere individuals find themselves in legalemergencies and self-insurance or privateinsurance are not viable opti<strong>on</strong>s. Providingfree legal representati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigent criminaldefendants is the most obvious example, butthere are other cases in this category as well.• Sec<strong>on</strong>d, when legal aid resources are scarce,it makes sense to rati<strong>on</strong> these resources sothat legal aid is targeted primarily at caseswhere the pursuit of the individual legal claimis more likely to benefit a larger class of disempoweredindividuals: 1) disputes wheredeterrence of future wr<strong>on</strong>gdoing is particularlyimportant; 2) ‘impact’ litigati<strong>on</strong> that seeksbroad instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m remedies or changesin the substantive law.• Third, governments and d<strong>on</strong>ors should encourageand facilitate the organisati<strong>on</strong> of localgroups that can provide legal representati<strong>on</strong>(or funding <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal representati<strong>on</strong>) to theirmembers. In many cases, governments andd<strong>on</strong>ors should funnel their legal insurancefunding through these groups rather than tryingto reach individuals directly. Local, community-basedrepresentative groups, much likethe rotating credit associati<strong>on</strong>s celebrated inthe literature <strong>on</strong> micro-finance, allow individualsto pool their risk and provide them with asource of financing in times of need. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seorganisati<strong>on</strong>s also provide more effective m<strong>on</strong>itoringand allocate resources more efficientlythan states or d<strong>on</strong>or organisati<strong>on</strong>s.Reducing Transacti<strong>on</strong> Costs:Wholesale Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> preceding secti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cluded with an analysisof the situati<strong>on</strong> where <strong>on</strong>e lawsuit creates benefits<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a large number of poor people. This is anexample of a more general strategy to look <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> approachesthat lead to ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. Like thebenefits of access to justice can spread over manypeople, there are also approaches that reduce thecosts of access to justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> many people at thesame time. A typical example is the costs thatresult from complex and archaic procedures thatserve little or no useful functi<strong>on</strong>. It is often cheaperto eliminate the source of such costs ‘wholesale’than it would be to provide ‘retail’ assistance toindividuals who want to use the system. Thus,when the diagnosis of the problem is high transacti<strong>on</strong>costs of using the legal system, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mersshould c<strong>on</strong>sider wholesale soluti<strong>on</strong>s as an alternative,or complement, to subsidised provisi<strong>on</strong> ofindividual-level legal services. Such soluti<strong>on</strong>s include:1) making the laws simpler, focusing accessto justice ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts <strong>on</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> problems the poor; 2)creating small claims courts with simplified proceduresthat do not require a lawyer’s assistance;and 3) allowing those with similar complaints tobring their cases up as a group or class. A fourthand more general strategy would be to find ec<strong>on</strong>o-36


mies of scale in the legal system.C<strong>on</strong>sider as a simple example, access to basicin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about the law. As we sawin many developing countries simply finding outwhat the law is can be a time-c<strong>on</strong>suming andcostly endeavour, because the laws are not availablein print, or <strong>on</strong>ly in a language not understoodby the poor. One way to ameliorate thesetransacti<strong>on</strong> cost barriers would be to provide orsubsidise legal service providers who are fluent inboth the nati<strong>on</strong>al language and the local vernacular.This approach, however, would be extraordinarilyexpensive. A more sensible soluti<strong>on</strong> wouldbe to translate the law into all significant locallanguages, to provide user-friendly terminologyor explanatory notes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> likely incomprehensibleterms and jarg<strong>on</strong>, to disseminate it widely, to ensurethat law is administered (to the extent possible)in the language of the relevant regi<strong>on</strong>, andto provide centralised translati<strong>on</strong> services wherethis is not possible (e.g. NCLEP Pakistan 2007,NCLEP Tanzania 2007, NCLEP Uganda 2007).While this set of approaches is not cost-free, it isa much cheaper way of reducing linguistic barriersto access than providing individual-level legalassistance. 5Standard Routes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Most Urgent <strong>Legal</strong> NeedsOne of the values instilled in law students allover the world is that soluti<strong>on</strong>s to legal problemsshould be highly c<strong>on</strong>textual, taking into accountevery aspect of the situati<strong>on</strong>. This ideal is alsoreflected in the way law firms and courts tend tobe organised. A case is assigned to a lawyer, or toa judge, who spends as many hours <strong>on</strong> the caseas the case needs. Although other billing methodsexist, most lawyers are paid by the hour, sothat they have fewer incentives than other similarservice providers to look <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> standardised soluti<strong>on</strong>sto similar problems. Standardisati<strong>on</strong> doesoccur in bigger law firms, but these are not verylikely to serve the poor.Compare this to doctors and other healthcareproviders, who increasingly work from protocolsthat reflect the best treatment practices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> comm<strong>on</strong>ailments. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se protocols are in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med byresearch and make implied trade-offs betweenquality (risk) and costs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> protocols are available<strong>on</strong> the Internet, so that clients can checkthem, and hold their doctors accountable if necessary.Like people come to doctors with moreor less standard problems, many legal problemsof individuals are rather similar. Terminati<strong>on</strong> ofemployment, changes in land use or rented housingarrangements, splitting up of families, deathof parents, terminati<strong>on</strong> of cooperati<strong>on</strong> betweenbusiness partners and expropriati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> propertydevelopment are the most comm<strong>on</strong> transiti<strong>on</strong>sin a life time. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y tend to lead to similar problemswith divisi<strong>on</strong> of property and redefiningrelati<strong>on</strong>ships in such a way that social capital ispreserved. Issues between husband and wife, betweenlandlord and tenant, between users of thesame source of water, or between employer andemployee follow certain comm<strong>on</strong> patterns as well.This creates possibilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale.Standard in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> leaflets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> clients can savethe costs of intake and leave clients better in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med.Best practices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the settlement processcan be designed. Rules of thumb <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> divisi<strong>on</strong> ofproperty can be defined, if necessary with standardexcepti<strong>on</strong>s when comm<strong>on</strong> reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> derogati<strong>on</strong>from the more general rule occur. Tradeuni<strong>on</strong>s can specialise in employment issues, andleave family issues to other specialists.However, policy makers should also investigatewhy this standardisati<strong>on</strong> does not happen sp<strong>on</strong>taneously.One possible reas<strong>on</strong> is that providersof justice services have little means to influ-37


ence others in the supply chain to accept moreefficient settlement and litigati<strong>on</strong> procedures.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir clients, often opp<strong>on</strong>ents in a c<strong>on</strong>flict, arenot very likely to cooperate in order to find themost efficient process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> incentives <strong>on</strong> lawyers,who are in a unique positi<strong>on</strong> as professi<strong>on</strong>alsbecause they can directly create work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> eachother, are very different from those in a normalsupply chain. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re, producers, distributors andclients all have the same incentives to cut thetransacti<strong>on</strong> costs, because there is an exposureto outside competiti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> incentives <strong>on</strong> judgesand other neutrals may also work against standardisati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y have no duty to the disputants tomake a trade-off between costs and quality whenthey organise the process through their decisi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> procedure, and in some legal systems they aresupposed to leave the management of the procedureto the parties.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se issues regarding the management of thejustice supply chain have, as far as the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ingGroup could establish, not yet been studied indepth (Hadfield 2000 is <strong>on</strong>e of the excepti<strong>on</strong>s).An open questi<strong>on</strong> is, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance, why legalservices to individuals tend to be per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med byindividual lawyers, or small partnerships, and notby bigger companies that offer standard services<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> comm<strong>on</strong> problems, such as is the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>banking and insurance. Another issue is wherethe resp<strong>on</strong>sibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the design and improvementof procedures should be located: Is this primarilythe task of the legislator, of the judiciary, or isthere a role here <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> bottom up processes as well?We now turn to this topic of improving the designof procedures Simplifying ProceduresAn attractive approach to reducing legal transacti<strong>on</strong>costs wholesale, rather than attempting tosubsidise these costs <strong>on</strong> a retail basis, would beto simplify the substantive and procedural law.One essential step could be to allow individualsto advance their legal claims without representati<strong>on</strong>in small claims courts or other morein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal tribunals (Lopez-de-Silanes 2002,Buscaglia and Ulen 1997). Adopting this approachis probably not without costs: Simplifyinglaws so that they can be understood and invokedby uneducated lay people may require makinglaws cruder, less nuanced, and less efficient,although some may argue that targeting lawsbetter to the problems of the poor may have theopposite effect. If the legislator has sufficientin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and background analysis regardingwhat c<strong>on</strong>stitute the most comm<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns andgrievances of poor people and other disadvantagedgroups, the substantive legislati<strong>on</strong> may betailored to be receptive to such grievances.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re may be several layers within pieces oflegislati<strong>on</strong> that aim at different target groupsensuring that principles of equality and n<strong>on</strong>discriminati<strong>on</strong>are adhered to, whilst <strong>on</strong> anotherlevel the legislati<strong>on</strong> is drafted in a sufficientlysophisticated manner to cater <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the needs <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>nuances and detail. Administering laws in smallclaims courts or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal tribunals entails dispensingwith some of the procedural safeguardsthat attend more <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal proceedings, andthe adjudicators in such <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ums may be lesscompetent. However, many of the legal issues ofpoor people are reas<strong>on</strong>ably simple in legal termsthe problem is that they are met with overtly andunnecessary completed procedures that <strong>on</strong>lywork to exclude the poor from justice settlementmechanisms.One way of dealing with this is to provide peoplewith ‘simple’ and ‘sophisticated’ procedures nextto each other. Poor plaintiffs will then be able tochoose the procedure they find is most appropriateto their problem and circumstances. However,this requires clear c<strong>on</strong>sumer in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, andnecessitates designing ‘simple’ procedures that38


at least meet certain quality thresholds.N<strong>on</strong>etheless, legal and adjudicative simplificati<strong>on</strong>may drastically reduce the transacti<strong>on</strong>costs of access to justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a very largenumber of potential c<strong>on</strong>sumers of justice services(NCLEP Tanzania 2007, NCLEP Uganda 2007).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> net social welfare gains associated with thisstrategy may be much larger than the net gainsassociated with trying to provide every needy individualwith sufficient legal aid to navigate thecomplexities of a more ‘sophisticated’ legal andjudicial system (Galanter 1976, Hay, Shleifer andVishny 1996, Posner 1998).General <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malistic court procedures may alsobe altered to accommodate poor people or peoplewho have had little c<strong>on</strong>tact with <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal statestructures be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e appearing in court. Archaicregulati<strong>on</strong>s regarding dress-codes, how to sit orstand, the set up of the court where the judgesand the officials of the court sit <strong>on</strong> a higher plateauthan the audience and the parties to thesuit, use of official language without necessaryinterpretati<strong>on</strong> into local languages are all featuresthat can easily be removed and interpretati<strong>on</strong> canbe organised with little extra resources.A potential political difficulty with these sorts ofwholesale instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms is that many ofthem reduce the demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the services offeredby attorneys or other legal professi<strong>on</strong>als; indeed,that is part of the point of such re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Thus,even when wholesale transacti<strong>on</strong>-cost reducingstrategies are efficient, they may provoke politicaloppositi<strong>on</strong>. For example, Brazil recently establishedsmall claims courts in which individualscan appear without having to retain counsel.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Brazilian Bar Associati<strong>on</strong> opposed the provisi<strong>on</strong>and is c<strong>on</strong>testing the legality of this aspectof the small claims court system (Hammergren2007). Similarly, the bar associati<strong>on</strong> in Uruguaystrenuously objected to transacti<strong>on</strong>-cost reducingre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that streamlined and expedited civiland criminal trials (Messick 1999). And whenPeru wanted to liberalise its property registrati<strong>on</strong>system to make it more accessible to low-incomePeruvians, lawyers and notaries objected becausethe re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms eliminated the m<strong>on</strong>opoly thatthe legal professi<strong>on</strong> previously had <strong>on</strong> verifyingand registering property ownership (World Bank1997). In other cases, though, organised bar associati<strong>on</strong>shave recognised the value of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msto reduce aggregate transacti<strong>on</strong> costs, and havebeen a powerful ally of pro-poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers. It isthere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e important to cultivate the support ofthe legal professi<strong>on</strong> when pursuing these sorts ofre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.Bundling Claims: Class Acti<strong>on</strong>sAnother important situati<strong>on</strong> in which the transacti<strong>on</strong>costs associated with individual-level legalservices may lead to failures in the legal servicesmarket involves situati<strong>on</strong>s is when many individualssuffer a relatively small injury from a comm<strong>on</strong>or similar source. In such cases the aggregateinjury to social welfare may be large, but no individualhas sufficient incentives to incur the costsof securing the legal services necessary to seekredress of the injury. While it would be possibleto address this problem by providing subsidisedlegal services to every individual who might havea valid legal claim, this approach is extremely inefficient.An alternative approach is to authorisesome <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of aggregate multi-party or representativelitigati<strong>on</strong>, so that a small number of legalservice providers can represent a large group ofsimilarly situated individual.One model <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> such litigati<strong>on</strong> is the class acti<strong>on</strong>mechanism widely used in the United States.While class acti<strong>on</strong>s have their flaws, the classacti<strong>on</strong> device has been a powerful tool in expand-39


ing access to justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> disadvantaged groups inthe United States (Bloom 2006). In the developingworld, class acti<strong>on</strong> suits have also producednotable successes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people in India, SouthAfrica, and elsewhere. Although class acti<strong>on</strong> suitsare less comm<strong>on</strong> in civil law jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s, recentlysome civil law countries, including Brazil andInd<strong>on</strong>esia, have begun to experiment with authorsclass acti<strong>on</strong> suits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> certain types of issues (Gidi2003). While these re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms have their problemsand detractors, there is some evidence that theclass acti<strong>on</strong> mechanism has improved access tojustice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. In Brazil, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, classacti<strong>on</strong>s against municipal governments have successfullychallenged illegal taxes and illegal fareincreases <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public busses. Brazilian plaintiffshave also successfully deployed class acti<strong>on</strong> litigati<strong>on</strong>against private companies to redress masswr<strong>on</strong>gs such as product defects, envir<strong>on</strong>mentaldamage, and abusive or deceptive marketingpractices (Gidi 2003).This is not to say that U.S., Indian, or Brazilianapproach to class acti<strong>on</strong> litigati<strong>on</strong> is the rightmodel. Rather, the point is that when large numbersof poor people are victims of the same orsimilar legal injury, it is prudent to design somesort of mechanism through which they can pursuetheir claims collectively, rather than requiringeach potential claimant to pursue her own claimseparately. That latter approach entails either awholesale denial of access to justice (if few or nopotential claimants are able to af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d adequatelegal representati<strong>on</strong>) or massive costs (if largenumbers of claimants pursue their individualclaims separately). One attractive political featureof expanding access to multi-party representativelitigati<strong>on</strong> is that, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to transacti<strong>on</strong>-costreducti<strong>on</strong> strategies that reduce demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalservices, expanding the availability of collectivelitigati<strong>on</strong> devices tends to increase the demand<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services and there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e should appeal tothe legal professi<strong>on</strong> (at least its more entrepreneurialmembers). Political oppositi<strong>on</strong> to this sortof re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is more likely to come from potentialtargets of class suits, including government agencies,municipalities, and large corporati<strong>on</strong>s.An alternative bundling mechanism to class acti<strong>on</strong>sthat also supports a c<strong>on</strong>trolled handlingof large numbers of similar (tort) claims is theestablishment of a compensati<strong>on</strong> fund. Compensati<strong>on</strong>funds usually provide fixed amounts ofcompensati<strong>on</strong> to injured parties in cases wherethe rules of (tort) law and/or the instituti<strong>on</strong>al legalinfrastructure functi<strong>on</strong> inadequately or functi<strong>on</strong>not at all, e.g. in post-war and post-disaster situati<strong>on</strong>s.Simple, user-friendly applicati<strong>on</strong> procedures,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance run by NGO’s in collaborati<strong>on</strong>with the local community and authorities, couldfacilitate people in need of basic subsistence torebuild their lives with m<strong>on</strong>etary and n<strong>on</strong>-m<strong>on</strong>etarymeans at relatively low transacti<strong>on</strong> costs.Other Ways to Reduce Costs of Access WholesaleStandardisati<strong>on</strong> of settlement and negotiati<strong>on</strong>processes, improving procedures, and bundlingclaims are but examples of ways to reduce transacti<strong>on</strong>costs wholesale and to raise the quality ofprocedures and outcomes. A substantial proporti<strong>on</strong>of the costs of access to justice comes from theprocess of finding, establishing and substantiatingthe facts. How extensive fact-finding should be,however, is a design issue <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> procedures, that isseldom addressed explicitly. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is an obvioustrade-off between the costs of the registrati<strong>on</strong> proceduresand processes to settle disputes or to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cerights and the costs of error if the wr<strong>on</strong>g factsare established. Requiring unnecessary documentsor evidence can be a serious barrier to access.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> issue of fact-finding is again related to theapplicable legal criteria and the way they are pro-40


duced. In most legal systems, the rules of privatelaw that determine the outcome of the most comm<strong>on</strong>disputes of the poor are rather open ended.Both in comm<strong>on</strong> law and in civil law countriescase law is supposed to generate more guidanceover time, but deciding and publishing cases <strong>on</strong>eby <strong>on</strong>e is not the <strong>on</strong>ly — and often not the mostefficient — way to procedure criteria that canhelp people to settle disputes. Neutral instituti<strong>on</strong>slike government commissi<strong>on</strong>s, committeesof judges, or academics can play a useful rolehere. An example is damage scheduling, whichguides the disputants and the judge when theyhave to establish the value of a pers<strong>on</strong>al injuryclaim without binding them. This is very comm<strong>on</strong>in European legal systems that have to dealwith pers<strong>on</strong>al injury claims. Such criteria mayreduce the costs of fact-finding substantially, canincrease transparency of the outcomes, and makesettlement easier to achieve (Bovbjerg et al.). Oneof the key issues here is that these rules act asa presumpti<strong>on</strong>, without sacrificing the possibilityto tailor the result to the specific circumstances,thus saving decisi<strong>on</strong> costs without a corresp<strong>on</strong>dingincrease in the costs of error (Schauer 1991,Kaplow 1992).Another example in which wholesale re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mmakes more sense than subsidising individual legaltransacti<strong>on</strong>s involves the legal documentati<strong>on</strong>of comm<strong>on</strong> transacti<strong>on</strong>s — such as sale, rental,and employment c<strong>on</strong>tracts — as well as comm<strong>on</strong>legal documents like wills, title registrati<strong>on</strong>s, andgovernment claim applicati<strong>on</strong>s. Securing the assistancenecessary to draft legally valid versi<strong>on</strong>sof these and other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal documents can be expensive.As a result, poor people may simply <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>egothe activity in questi<strong>on</strong> (which is inefficient),may <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ego legal documentati<strong>on</strong> (which is risky),or, in the case of transacti<strong>on</strong>s with a more sophisticatedparty, may rely <strong>on</strong> documents provided bythat party (which might lead to exploitati<strong>on</strong>).One soluti<strong>on</strong> to this problem is to provideretail legal aid services, provided either bylawyers or paralegals. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> advantage of this approachis that the legal service can be tailored tothe individual client’s needs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> disadvantage,however, is that this client-by-client approach isextremely expensive. Another drawback of <strong>on</strong>e<strong>on</strong>-<strong>on</strong>eservices especially in comm<strong>on</strong>ly occurringlegal needs is the n<strong>on</strong>-profitability of the service<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the larger community. An alternative strategymight be <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> local lawyers, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> withcivil society groups and other community-basedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s like local councils, chambers ofcommerce, banks, am<strong>on</strong>g others, am<strong>on</strong>g others,to draft and disseminate standard-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m documents<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> comm<strong>on</strong> legal transacti<strong>on</strong>s and provideeducati<strong>on</strong> and outreach explaining the significanceof the documents. This approach sacrificesindividual tailoring in the interests of exploitingec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. However, it facilitates sharingthe benefits of legal services am<strong>on</strong>gst groups ofcitizens in comparable situati<strong>on</strong>s at lower costs.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> bottom-line message is: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> inability of poorpeople to access the legal system is frequentlythe result of the transacti<strong>on</strong> costs associated withthe pursuit of valid legal claims. It is often thecase that many individuals face similar transacti<strong>on</strong>costs arising from a comm<strong>on</strong> source, orwould have to pay similar transacti<strong>on</strong> costs toseek redress of a comm<strong>on</strong> legal injury or problem.In the presence of such aggregate or redundantlegal transacti<strong>on</strong> costs, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers should try toaddress the problem at the wholesale level, ratherthan focusing exclusively <strong>on</strong> the provisi<strong>on</strong> ofretail-level legal aid services or neutral disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong> to individuals. Wholesale re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategiesinclude both re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that eliminate thesource of significant legal transacti<strong>on</strong> costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>large numbers of individuals (e.g., legal stand-41


ardisati<strong>on</strong> and simplificati<strong>on</strong>) and also re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msthat enable large numbers of potential claimantsto pool their resources to pursue their comm<strong>on</strong>legal interests rather than <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing them all to pursuetheir individual claims separately (e.g., classacti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms).Improving In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and CustomaryDispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> 6Most poor people — especially the poorest of thepoor — have little or no c<strong>on</strong>tact with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallegal system, and are not likely to do so even ifall aspects of the legal empowerment agendaare implemented. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y instead seek justice fromcustomary law (which may be highly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisedand is sometimes officially recognised by thestate system) and from in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal norms, practices,religi<strong>on</strong>s and instituti<strong>on</strong>s. For example, in sub-Saharan Africa, customary land tenure law coversroughly 75 percent of land and in some countries,such as Mozambique and Ghana, over 90percent of land transacti<strong>on</strong>s are governed by customarylaw (Wojkowska 2006). In urban shantytownsin Columbia, squatters who cannot rely <strong>on</strong>the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system because of their illegal statushave established in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal urban justice systemsto deal with disputes and provide basic services(Faundez 2006). Traditi<strong>on</strong>al and modern civilsociety instituti<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>tinue to play an importantrole in local dispute settlement in Afghanistan.Traditi<strong>on</strong>al decisi<strong>on</strong> making assemblies are estimatedto account <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> more than 80 percent ofcases settled throughout Afghanistan (AfghanistanHDR 2007). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se examples are merelyisolated illustrati<strong>on</strong>s of a much more pervasivephenomen<strong>on</strong>: the predominance of n<strong>on</strong>-state justicesystems as the primary mode of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>in the lived experience of the overwhelmingmajority of the world’s poor.One element of the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment’s agenda,of course, is to enable more poor people tomake the transiti<strong>on</strong> from the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector tothe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal, while at the same time integratinguseful norms and practices from in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or customarysystems. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se approaches are discussedin detail in the chapters prepared by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’sworking groups <strong>on</strong> property rights, labour,and business, and we will, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, not focus<strong>on</strong> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malizati<strong>on</strong> of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector or <strong>on</strong>facilitating the transiti<strong>on</strong> from the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sectorto the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal. Formalizati<strong>on</strong> is not always possible,however, and indeed, not always desirable, asthe other working groups discuss in detail in theirchapters within this volume. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice systemsmay be more culturally familiar, more easilyaccessible, cheaper, and better tailored to localcircumstances than the state-run legal system.Poor people may also be more willing to use n<strong>on</strong>statejustice systems because of a general distrustor fear of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal state instituti<strong>on</strong>s, includingthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice system (NCLEP Uganda 2007).For these and other reas<strong>on</strong>s, many countries haveopted to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally recognise, or tacitly accept, thelegitimacy of customary law in certain geographicregi<strong>on</strong>s or substantive areas. And some systemsare <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally integrated in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal systemand reflected in substantive legislati<strong>on</strong> and thestructure of the judiciary. Regulati<strong>on</strong>s have alsobeen enacted to provide <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal procedures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>what legal system to chose and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> how far thecustomary system may reach in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal judiciaryand justice system. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or customarysystems, of course, have serious problems, and itwould be a mistake to romanticize or glamorizethem. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and customary law can be oppressiveto women. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are almost totally excludedfrom participating in the decisi<strong>on</strong> making ofjirgas/shuras resulting in serious c<strong>on</strong>sequences<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their status and the protecti<strong>on</strong> of their rights(Afghanistan HDR 2007). In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal systems may42


also exclude other disadvantaged social groups,may perpetuate the power of local elites andstifle dissent, and may be unsuited to rapidec<strong>on</strong>omic development (NCLEP Uganda 2007).Just as poor communities may find it difficult toaccess <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice instituti<strong>on</strong>s, marginalizedmembers of poor communities may find it difficultto achieve equal access to the instituti<strong>on</strong>sof customary or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice (NCLEP India2007, NCLEP Philippines 2007). N<strong>on</strong>etheless,despite these problems, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers must acknowledgethat in many situati<strong>on</strong>s replacing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal orcustomary justice systems with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legalor bureaucratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s of the state is eitherimpossible or would do more harm than good.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, al<strong>on</strong>gside programmes to improvethe state justice systems, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers should seekout opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> strategic interventi<strong>on</strong>s thatimprove the operati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or customaryjustice systems and facilitate the efficient integrati<strong>on</strong>of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal systems.Ultimately, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms and improvements to then<strong>on</strong>-state justice system must emerge ‘bottomup’from the participants in that system. Whilea government’s role in facilitating re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of n<strong>on</strong>statejustice systems is necessarily limited, itcan (perhaps in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with internati<strong>on</strong>ald<strong>on</strong>ors working through government) take acti<strong>on</strong>sto influence the development of n<strong>on</strong>-statejustice systems. We may group them under fourcategories: educati<strong>on</strong> and awareness campaigns;tailored legal aid services; targeted c<strong>on</strong>straints,and structuring instituti<strong>on</strong>al relati<strong>on</strong>ships.Educati<strong>on</strong> and Awareness CampaignsEmpowering the poor to demand changes in thecustomary system is the first approach. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merscan encourage trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> from within simplyby providing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about individuals’ legalrights under the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> and about the normsof the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system. In Bangladesh, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, the C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>bids the practice o<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>al divorce, but in poor rural communities, thepractice is still widespread. A Bangladeshi NGOfound that simply in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the members of localcustomary courts that oral divorce was <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>biddenby the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> substantially reduced thepractice. More generally, this NGO found that itwas possible to introduce norms from nati<strong>on</strong>allaw into community deliberati<strong>on</strong>s and mediati<strong>on</strong>practices otherwise based <strong>on</strong> customary law andtraditi<strong>on</strong>al norms (Golub 2000).Although this may be an excepti<strong>on</strong>al case,educati<strong>on</strong> and awareness-raising campaignsmay have l<strong>on</strong>g term effects <strong>on</strong> the evoluti<strong>on</strong> ofcustomary law systems. This effect may be particularlypowerful if educati<strong>on</strong>al ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts are coupledwith improved access to the state system as analternative to the customary system. Customary legalofficials who want to retain their authority maythen feel some competitive pressure to modifythe norms of the customary system to align themmore closely with those of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system. Educati<strong>on</strong>ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts are not likely to reap visible shorttermbenefits, but in the l<strong>on</strong>ger term they mayeffect significant change in cultural practices.A variant of the educati<strong>on</strong>-oriented approach isto provide in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> how other customarycourts have resolved similar disputes. Implementingschemes that let customary officials anddisputants in customary systems know how othercustomary courts have resolved similar issuesmay encourage c<strong>on</strong>sistency, limit abuse, and allow<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the gradual evoluti<strong>on</strong> of the customarysystem. This is not to say that customary legalsystems should be c<strong>on</strong>verted into comm<strong>on</strong> lawstyle courts with binding precedent. Rather, thesuggesti<strong>on</strong> is that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> sharing not <strong>on</strong>lyabout the norms of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system, butalso about the norms adopted by other custom-43


ary or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal systems, may improve the overallfuncti<strong>on</strong>ing of the system and empower poor peopleto challenge customary practices that seemlike arbitrary abuses of power.Tailored <strong>Legal</strong> Aid ServicesMost government and d<strong>on</strong>or sp<strong>on</strong>sored ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts toprovide more legal services to the poor emphasiseaccess to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system. Hence,a significant fracti<strong>on</strong> of legal aid resources aretargeted at subsidising lawyers or reducing costsassociated with using the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal court system.But as it turns out, many poor people tend torely <strong>on</strong> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or customary justice systems. Intheory, these alternatives may be more familiarand accessible; but in practice, many poor people— particularly women, young people, and membersof other disadvantaged groups — may alsofind it difficult and intimidating to navigate thecustomary system. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se vulnerable individualsmay also be subject to abuses by the local eliteswho administer traditi<strong>on</strong>al justice systems.Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers should, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, c<strong>on</strong>sider targetinglegal aid resources and legal service providerswho can help poor people deal with both thecustomary and the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal state system. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>paralegal programme in Sierra Le<strong>on</strong>e discussedearlier is exemplary in this regard (Maru 2006).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se paralegals have a basic training in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallaw, but they are also drawn from the local communityand are familiar with local traditi<strong>on</strong>s andcustomary law. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y can there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e assist clientswith the n<strong>on</strong>-state justice system. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y can alsom<strong>on</strong>itor abuses, and are better positi<strong>on</strong>ed to adviseclients <strong>on</strong> when they should threaten to takea dispute to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal state system. Particularlyin light of the fact that markets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-state justice instituti<strong>on</strong>s are typicallythin or n<strong>on</strong>-existent, legal aid resources maybe especially productive when focused <strong>on</strong> subsidisingthis sort of representati<strong>on</strong>.Targeted C<strong>on</strong>straints <strong>on</strong> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Justice<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> trying toreap the benefits of n<strong>on</strong>-state justice while avoidingits flaws is to accept (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally or tacitly) thelegitimacy of n<strong>on</strong>-state justice systems withincertain limits, but to strategically and aggressivelyintervene to require the n<strong>on</strong>-state systemto respect certain fundamental norms that mightotherwise c<strong>on</strong>flict with traditi<strong>on</strong>al practices. Thatis, instead of attempting to displace or <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malizethe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system entirely, government re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mersmight selectively impose a relatively smallnumber of especially important norms <strong>on</strong> the customarysystem.This approach is appealing because it seems toreflect a reas<strong>on</strong>able compromise between theinterest in preserving and promoting n<strong>on</strong>-statedispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> and the interest in respectingfundamental c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al principles and humanrights norms. This proposed compromise, however,immediately raises the questi<strong>on</strong> of exactlywhich norms are so fundamental that they musttake precedence over in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or customary practices.Because this questi<strong>on</strong> implicates the appropriatedesign of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal laws <strong>on</strong> topics includingproperty, labour, and business activity, ourchapter does not cover this aspect of the problemin detail. It is worth emphasising, however, thatthe most prominent and difficult set of questi<strong>on</strong>sc<strong>on</strong>cerning the degree to which <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal law shouldtrump in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal law c<strong>on</strong>cerns the status of womenand domestic relati<strong>on</strong>s.Despite the fact that many customary systemsclaim that the subordinati<strong>on</strong> of women is c<strong>on</strong>sistentwith traditi<strong>on</strong>al cultural practices, this is <strong>on</strong>earea where the state should be more aggressivein limiting their authority. Taking a str<strong>on</strong>g standagainst gender discriminati<strong>on</strong> in customary sys-44


tems is important both <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> intrinsic moral reas<strong>on</strong>s— reflected in the human rights principles laidout in the C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Eliminati<strong>on</strong> of AllForms of Discriminati<strong>on</strong> Against Women — and<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> pragmatic ec<strong>on</strong>omic reas<strong>on</strong>s. This is in lightof the growing body of research that genderequality and women’s empowerment fosters sustainableec<strong>on</strong>omic growth and promotes healthand educati<strong>on</strong>.South Africa and Tanzania both offer powerfulrecent examples of cases where the state hasrecognised the legitimacy of customary law up toa point, but has required that customary systemschange to respect the equal rights and status ofwomen. In South Africa, NGOs successfully lobbied<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the passage of a ‘Recogniti<strong>on</strong> of CustomaryMarriages Act’ that <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally recognised marriagesc<strong>on</strong>cluded in accordance of customary law,but <strong>on</strong>ly if customary law provided <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> equality ofhusband and wife in terms of status, decisi<strong>on</strong>makingauthority, property ownership, and childcustody (Centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Applied <strong>Legal</strong> Studies 2002).Tanzania has enacted two Land Acts that c<strong>on</strong>fer<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal recogniti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> customary title, but alsomandate the eliminati<strong>on</strong> of customary practicesthat discriminate against women with respectto land ownership (Ikdahl et al. 2005, Tsikata2003). Neither the South African nor the Tanzanianlaws have been implemented perfectly, andcustomary gender discriminati<strong>on</strong> is still a pervasiveproblem in both countries, but these experimentsn<strong>on</strong>etheless suggest that it is possible toenact re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m built around a political compromise:<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal recogniti<strong>on</strong> of customary law in exchange<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rejecti<strong>on</strong> of certain customary norms thatare repugnant to principles of n<strong>on</strong>-discriminati<strong>on</strong>and gender equality.Another less<strong>on</strong> of both the South African andTanzanian experiences is that these sorts of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mstrategies cannot be imposed immediatelyfrom the top down. Where cultural practices anddiscriminatory attitudes are deeply entrenched,successful legislative re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m requires sustainedc<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>, lobbying, and political organisingef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts. Also, in some cases the pursuit of genderequity goals might need to be tempered bypragmatic c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s, and it might be betterto pursue a gradual re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategy that starts bytargeting <strong>on</strong>ly the most extreme <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of genderdiscriminati<strong>on</strong>, and then progressively expandingthe scope of this anti-discriminati<strong>on</strong> principle. Asthe example in Box 2 shows, a complex legal universegoverns the legal positi<strong>on</strong> of poor women inmany developing countries. This example furtherilluminates the effect of legal regimes in the fieldof inheritance and property rights of women andits effects <strong>on</strong> the prevalence of and societal situati<strong>on</strong>with regard to HIV/AIDS.While the implementati<strong>on</strong> strategy will vary bycountry, targeted interventi<strong>on</strong>s to eliminate discriminatorypractices — particularly gender-baseddiscriminati<strong>on</strong> — should be a prerequisite towidespread recogniti<strong>on</strong> or acceptance of customarydispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> systems.Structuring Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Relati<strong>on</strong>ships<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government can also influence access tojustice in n<strong>on</strong>-state instituti<strong>on</strong>s by structuringthe instituti<strong>on</strong>al relati<strong>on</strong>ship between the stateand n<strong>on</strong>-state justice systems. One basic issuethe government must c<strong>on</strong>sider is whether to give<strong>on</strong>e justice system exclusive jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> over aparticular class of disputes, or whether disputantshave the opti<strong>on</strong> of choosing between differentsystems. (<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> absence of choice may be de jure— as when the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal law gives customary courtsin a particular area have exclusive jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>over family relati<strong>on</strong>s or property disputes — or defacto — as when the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal court system is so45


Box 2 Coping with <strong>Legal</strong> Pluralism in Relati<strong>on</strong> to Women’s Rightsin EthiopiaIn the Amhara regi<strong>on</strong> in Ethiopia, photographs of bothhusband and wife are required <strong>on</strong> the land title. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>provisi<strong>on</strong> also restricts <strong>on</strong>e spouse from selling or inany other way transfer the property without the knowledgeof the other. This also reduces c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong> that mayoccur at the death of <strong>on</strong>e spouse. Although Ethiopia isquite advanced from a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal perspective, theissue of women’s inheritance and property rights is stillcomplex. This is dem<strong>on</strong>strated <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance through theinter-relati<strong>on</strong>ship between the HIV/AIDS epidemic andwomen’s property and inheritance rights. Comparatively,a ten-country study <strong>on</strong> women’s inheritance rightsin sub-Saharan Africa suggests that unequal housing,property and inheritance rights increase women’svulnerability to HIV, because it is, in part, why womenremain in abusive marriages. Moreover women areoften blamed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the deaths of their husbands and subsequently<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced from the household and left destitute.If they remain in the household, they are treated asservants or are married off to the father, uncle, brotheror another close male relative — a practice known as“wife inheritance.”To address the issue of HIV and women’s inheritanceand property rights an initiative was launched. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>aim was to build the capacity of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maljustice systems, to generate individual and collectiveacti<strong>on</strong> and to empower women in gaining equaltreatment in owning and inheriting property. A comprehensiveanalysis of the legal framework was carriedout which included a review of the statutory, civil andcustomary laws. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> study provided a solid empiricalfoundati<strong>on</strong> and underlined the strength of Ethiopianlaw. However, the substantive laws are not being appliedor en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced. This is a result of a number of factors,including lack of awareness, lack of en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementand ineffectiveness of the court system. Additi<strong>on</strong>alchallenges include a lengthy and costly legal process,which most Ethiopians cannot af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d, cultural barriers,free legal services are not yet readily available; the fearof being shunned and stigmatised by both family andsociety; and c<strong>on</strong>flicting laws which cause c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong> ordiscriminati<strong>on</strong> against women.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>flict between religious law and c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>allaw has also come to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e. It stems from a clausein the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> which recognises the adjudicati<strong>on</strong>of pers<strong>on</strong>al and family matters under religiousor customary law, if both parties agree. Article 34(5)of the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> states [<strong>on</strong> Marital, Pers<strong>on</strong>al andFamily Rights], ‘This C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> shall not precludethe adjudicati<strong>on</strong> of disputes relating to pers<strong>on</strong>al andfam-ily laws in accordance with religious or customarylaws, with the c<strong>on</strong>sent of the parties to the dispute.’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>flict arises out of provisi<strong>on</strong>s in the Shariá lawthat c<strong>on</strong>tradict the terms set <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>th in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>.In reality, women are sometimes coerced into ‘c<strong>on</strong>senting’by pressure from family or society. Although thesechallenges exist, Ethiopia is surpassing neighbouringcountries in the sense that they do not need to createnew laws or re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m archaic <strong>on</strong>es. Initiatives and campaignshave been set in moti<strong>on</strong> to counteract some ofthe problems and to resp<strong>on</strong>d to the challenges that aredem<strong>on</strong>strating encouraging signs.expensive and inaccessible that customary lawis the <strong>on</strong>ly af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable opti<strong>on</strong>.) Some have arguedthat integrating the customary system of disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong> into the mainstream legal system maybe an effective way to import desirable features ofthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system — including norms of genderequality and regularity — into the more accessiblecustomary system (NCLEP Uganda 2007).Others praise NGO ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts that have not focused<strong>on</strong> a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal integrati<strong>on</strong> of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsystems (Golub 2007), such as the Bangladeshiprogrammes that have taken up the issue of legalempowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women (UNDP 2002). Rather,some of these ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts have used the threat or realityof litigati<strong>on</strong> (that is, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system) as anincentive <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> resistant or recalcitrant parties to46


participate in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> suchparties to h<strong>on</strong>our agreements they have made. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>de facto impact has been to increase women’spower and well-being in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal systems that arevery gradually becoming less gender-biased.When there is overlapping jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> betweenlegal systems, a sec<strong>on</strong>d issue arises:What should the rules be <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> choosing a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>umand selecting the appropriate law to apply? Although<strong>on</strong>e must be cautious in offering c<strong>on</strong>clusiveanswers to these general questi<strong>on</strong>s, a usefulgeneral presumpti<strong>on</strong> is that individuals shouldalways be able to opt into the state system in theearly stages of a dispute, and they should be ableto challenge decisi<strong>on</strong>s of the n<strong>on</strong>-state systemthat are repugnant to fundamental human rightsprinciples. However, disputants who have electedto have a dispute resolved through the customarysystem should not be able to seek to undo anadverse judgment by re-litigating the dispute inthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal court system. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are basic principlestypically applied to ADR systems, and whilethey may not be universally applicable, they tendto promote efficiency, fairness, and healthy instituti<strong>on</strong>alcompetiti<strong>on</strong>.4. Improving Access toJustice in the GovernmentBureaucracy<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nature of the Problem<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> preceding secti<strong>on</strong> focused <strong>on</strong> access to the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal (adjudicative) legal system and to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maljustice mechanisms. But courts and out-of-courtfacilities are not the <strong>on</strong>ly instituti<strong>on</strong>s that en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceindividual rights and resolve disputes. A greatdeal of such work is d<strong>on</strong>e by public bureaucracies,especially in the c<strong>on</strong>text of governmentregulati<strong>on</strong> and service delivery, do a great dealof such work. Often the first (and sometimes the<strong>on</strong>ly) line of defence individuals have againstgovernment abuses and threatening or already encounteredinjustices from neighbours, the widercommunity or companies is through the bureaucraticsystem. If that system is not adequatelyaccessible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> and resp<strong>on</strong>sive to the needs andinterests of poor individuals, then it will not bepossible to legally empower the poor throughbureaucratic means. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, it is important toc<strong>on</strong>sider the problem of access to bureaucraticjustice.One of the most important public bureaucracies,and the <strong>on</strong>e which has great impact <strong>on</strong> the livesof many poor communities, is the police <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce.Public order and security are essential publicgoods, and a well-functi<strong>on</strong>ing law en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementapparatus is necessary to provide individuals witha stable and orderly living envir<strong>on</strong>ment and toprotect them from violence and exploitati<strong>on</strong>. Yetall too often the police not <strong>on</strong>ly do not provideadequate protecti<strong>on</strong> to vulnerable communities,but are themselves perpetrators of violence andexploitati<strong>on</strong> (Anders<strong>on</strong> 2003).In additi<strong>on</strong> to law en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement, state bureaucra-47


cies (including local authorities) are also resp<strong>on</strong>sible<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> providing a variety of other services,including clean water, health care, educati<strong>on</strong>,transportati<strong>on</strong>, infrastructure, and social insurance.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> degree to which these and other servicesshould be supplied by the state rather than themarket is a subject of c<strong>on</strong>siderable c<strong>on</strong>troversy,and not a matter <strong>on</strong> which a positi<strong>on</strong> is takenhere. Even when these services are supplied in acompetitive market, it is almost always a marketthat is regulated by some public bureaucracy.Indeed, in most countries the provisi<strong>on</strong> of accessto a competitive market is — perhaps paradoxically— the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of government regulatoryagencies.Yet all of these public bureaucracies may bevulnerable to a variety of ‘government failures’,analogous in some respects to the ‘market failures’discussed earlier. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> great variety of governmentfailures can be grouped into three majorcategories: malfeasance, underper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance, andincompetence.‘Malfeasance’ is the tendency of bureaucrats,or bureaucratic organisati<strong>on</strong>s, to abuse theirpower to pursue illegitimate goals. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mostwell-known and comprehensively studied <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ofbureaucratic malfeasance in poor countries is, ofcourse, corrupti<strong>on</strong> (Shleifer and Vishny 1993).Public officials may demand bribes, may showfavouritism to family or friends, or may use theirpower vindictively against pers<strong>on</strong>al enemies.Powerful incumbent politicians may also viewthe bureaucracy as a tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> entrenching theirown power rather than a means <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improvingpublic welfare. Whatever the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of malfeasance,the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor are fairly similar:deprivati<strong>on</strong> of services, of (avenues to) sharedpower, and of security. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se problems are pervasiveand much discussed throughout the developingworld. Malfeasance may also take moresubtle <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. For example, even well-meaningbureaucrats may be pr<strong>on</strong>e to subc<strong>on</strong>sciousprejudices resulting in a c<strong>on</strong>tinuous neglect ofcertain interests or measures with unintendeddiscriminatory effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> certain groups. Also,when certain groups are more effective at mobilisingresources to influence bureaucratic decisi<strong>on</strong>-making,public decisi<strong>on</strong>s may be distortedin favour of these groups, even if the bureaucraticdecisi<strong>on</strong>-makers are not c<strong>on</strong>sciously biased,and even if these interest groups are acting legallyand in good faith.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d category of bureaucratic failure,‘underper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance’, refers to the tendencyof even well-meaning bureaucrats to pursue theirmissi<strong>on</strong>s with a socially insufficient level of ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t(Bueno de Mesquita and Stephens<strong>on</strong> 2007). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>basic problem is that the rewards a bureaucratreceives are imperfectly correlated to how hardshe works or how well she per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. As a result,bureaucrats may be slow to complete tasks or resp<strong>on</strong>dto inquiries, and may have weak incentivesto figure out how to improve the overall efficiencyof the system, preferring to rely <strong>on</strong> pre-existingapproaches to new problems rather than puttingin the time and ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t to come up with better<strong>on</strong>es. Another <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of underper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance thatderives from the same basic incentive problem isinsufficient bureaucratic resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to c<strong>on</strong>sumerinput or c<strong>on</strong>sumer complaints. Even hardworking,public-spirited bureaucrats may becomedemoralized and give up if they feel like mostmembers of their organisati<strong>on</strong> are more interestedin leisure than in innovati<strong>on</strong>.Third, bureaucratic organisati<strong>on</strong>s may simplylack the competence or capacity to achieve theirassigned tasks, even when the bureaucrats themselvesare well-motivated (Huber and McCarty2004). Bureaucratic competence depends <strong>on</strong>a variety of factors, including the talent level of48


the individual bureaucrats, budgetary resources,the design of bureaucratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s and procedures,and appropriate feedback and accountabilitymechanisms. Where some or all of theseare deficient, government bureaucracies will notbe successful.Where the government bureaucracies that aresupposed to deliver services and protecti<strong>on</strong>s tothe poor suffer from malfeasance, underper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance,or incompetence problems, and the poorare powerless to change this. Remedying thissituati<strong>on</strong> requires re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m al<strong>on</strong>g two related dimensi<strong>on</strong>s:• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first dimensi<strong>on</strong> is public administrati<strong>on</strong>:How can we design bureaucracies that per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mtheir assigned functi<strong>on</strong>s with integrity, ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t,and resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to their clients? How canwe structure service processes, bureaucraticgrievance and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> proceduresthat are fair, efficient and user-focused?• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d dimensi<strong>on</strong> of bureaucratic justicere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m involves administrative law: What setof legal rules and procedures will empower thebureaucracy to achieve its goals while simultaneouslyc<strong>on</strong>straining potential abuses of power?What is the proper degree of judicial andpolitical oversight of government agencies?Public Administrati<strong>on</strong> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mTo improve access to bureaucratic justice throughre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of public administrati<strong>on</strong>, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers shouldwork to strengthen external m<strong>on</strong>itoring and toimplement structural re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that will improvebureaucratic incentives and capabilities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>right mix of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategies will vary depending<strong>on</strong> the political and instituti<strong>on</strong>al circumstances indifferent countries, and will also have to take intoaccount the specific social and cultural c<strong>on</strong>text.N<strong>on</strong>etheless, experience in a variety of countriessuggests that there are some general less<strong>on</strong>s tobe drawn about the types of public administrati<strong>on</strong>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m that may be appropriate.External M<strong>on</strong>itoringEffective and resp<strong>on</strong>sive public administrati<strong>on</strong>often requires m<strong>on</strong>itoring by entities outside thebureaucracy, including the intended recipientsof bureaucratic services, the general public, andother government agencies.One instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m that many countries haveimplemented to improve m<strong>on</strong>itoring is the establishmentof an independent ombudsman’s officeto resp<strong>on</strong>d to complaints and investigate allegati<strong>on</strong>sof malfeasance. In Peru, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, theombudsman was able to resolve a dispute involvingallegati<strong>on</strong>s that an agency had overchargedc<strong>on</strong>sumers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> electricity and teleph<strong>on</strong>e services:After the ombudsman investigated, issued areport, and credibly threatened litigati<strong>on</strong>, theagency took acti<strong>on</strong> to address the c<strong>on</strong>sumer complaints.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> effectiveness of an ombudsman may,as this case illustrates, depend <strong>on</strong> backgroundinstituti<strong>on</strong>s such as an effective court system thatgive other agencies an incentive to take theombudsman’s recommendati<strong>on</strong>s seriously.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> effectiveness of ombudsman offices mayalso depend <strong>on</strong> their resources. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Philippines,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, has an ombudsman’s office that isc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>ally very powerful, but chr<strong>on</strong>ic underfundinghas rendered it less effective in practice.Similarly, although the Pakistani ombudsman hassecured relief <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> some victims of maladministrati<strong>on</strong>and has been hailed as <strong>on</strong>e of the most successfulinstruments of the Pakistani governmentin serving the people, the number of complaintslodged has increased dramatically making the officegreatly overburdened. It has also been unableto address systematic bureaucratic failures thatgo bey<strong>on</strong>d the resoluti<strong>on</strong> of individual disputes49


(ADB 2001b). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se and other examples suggestthat while an ombudsman or and similar instituti<strong>on</strong>aldevice may be helpful, it is not a panacea.Other legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms may improveaccess to bureaucratic justice by aidingthe ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts of private individuals and organisati<strong>on</strong>sto m<strong>on</strong>itor the bureaucracy. Educating poorcommunities about their rights and means ofredress vis-à-vis the bureaucracy is an importantfirst step in ensuring bureaucratic accountability.Providing legal or quasi-legal assistance is another.Both of these issues are versi<strong>on</strong>s of the moregeneral issue of how to provide access to legalin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and legal services, discussed earlierin this chapter. However, particularly in caseswhere legal service providers support the publicagainst state behaviour, attenti<strong>on</strong> must be paid toinstituti<strong>on</strong>al arrangements which protect the independenceof justice services providers, becausesuch services will inevitably be more threateningto the state than, say, health or educati<strong>on</strong>.Government agencies can and should take additi<strong>on</strong>alsteps to facilitate m<strong>on</strong>itoring of bureaucraticper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance. For example, bureaucraciesshould employ an accessible case tracking system,which individuals and organisati<strong>on</strong>s canuse to m<strong>on</strong>itor the progress of disputes throughthe bureaucratic system. USAID helped developa case tracking system in Bosnia-Herzegovinathat allows civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s to m<strong>on</strong>itorcases at various stages in the administrativeprocess and to draw the attenti<strong>on</strong> of resp<strong>on</strong>sibleauthorities to cases that have been ignored orseem to be languishing in the system without aresoluti<strong>on</strong> (USAID 2006). Another approach thatcan c<strong>on</strong>tribute to increased public accountabilityis the introducti<strong>on</strong> of citizen charters, which arepreferably developed in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with thecommunity. Citizen’s charters should c<strong>on</strong>tainclear standards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance that are fit to bemeasured and benchmarked by the bureaucracy,independent agencies and the community itself.In this way the public has a yardstick <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> assessingpublic service delivery. An illustrative bottomup example of the citizenry measuring publicper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance are the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts of citizens’ groups inBangalore, India — these groups c<strong>on</strong>ducted c<strong>on</strong>sumersurveys regarding the per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance of localgovernment agencies and published the resultsin order to create pressure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. This ‘namingand shaming’ approach spread to other statesin India as well (Narayan 2002). Where feasible,modern in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> technology (e.g. Internet, cellph<strong>on</strong>es, etc.) could be used to disseminate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> bureaucratic per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance more broadly,which would facilitate external m<strong>on</strong>itoring.Structural Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msAs useful as it may be to improve external m<strong>on</strong>itoringmechanisms, significant progress towardimproving access to bureaucratic justice may requiremore systematic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of the bureaucraticinstituti<strong>on</strong>s themselves. A starting point is theimprovement of each agency’s internal adjudicativeprocedures, m<strong>on</strong>itoring mechanisms, appealsprocesses, and grievance procedures. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrativedispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> system and the publicinterventi<strong>on</strong>s aimed at facilitating the resoluti<strong>on</strong>of disputes between private parties do not alwaysreceive as much attenti<strong>on</strong> from governments andthe d<strong>on</strong>or community as the judicial system, butmore people — and a larger proporti<strong>on</strong> of poorpeople — are more likely to come into c<strong>on</strong>tactwith the bureaucratic system than the court system.(This would certainly be true of n<strong>on</strong>-criminalmatters.) Government bureaucracies resp<strong>on</strong>sible<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> delivering essential services and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> interventi<strong>on</strong>sin relati<strong>on</strong>ships between citizens shouldhave a well-functi<strong>on</strong>ing system <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> providingen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement and mediati<strong>on</strong> services, addressingcomplaints, resolving disputes, and providing50


edress. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se systems should be cost-efficient,transparent, user-friendly and swift.Asec<strong>on</strong>d strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> making public bureaucraciesmore resp<strong>on</strong>sive to the needs of poorcommunities is increasing the participati<strong>on</strong> ofpoor communities, or the public generally, in bureaucraticdecisi<strong>on</strong> making. Participatory methodssuch as interest-based dialogs, c<strong>on</strong>sensusbuilding, and public collaborati<strong>on</strong> aim to activelyengage people in decisi<strong>on</strong>-making processes thatc<strong>on</strong>cern their lives (Vidoga, 2002). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> possibilitiesto have input, to voice c<strong>on</strong>cerns, to makerecommendati<strong>on</strong>s and to co-produce outcomesare likely to improve the quality of public decisi<strong>on</strong>s.Participati<strong>on</strong> further increases the public’sunderstanding and acceptance of decisi<strong>on</strong>s, andadvances a sound partnership between the bureaucracyand the citizenry. An interesting exampleof participatory regulatory decisi<strong>on</strong> making isthe system of municipal water regulati<strong>on</strong> in PortoAlegre, Brazil. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> municipality wholly owns thePorto Alegre Municipal Department of Water andSewage, but it is a separate legal entity with financialand operati<strong>on</strong>al aut<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mayor appointsthe Department’s general director, but itsmanagement board includes representatives froma wide range of civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s. PortoAlegre also uses a participatory budgeting processin which citizens register their vote <strong>on</strong> budgetpriorities after hearing presentati<strong>on</strong>s from thedirectors of different service departments. Overall,this arrangement appears to have succeededin creating incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> high-quality service delivery(UNDP 2006).Other countries have also experimented with participatoryregulatory decisi<strong>on</strong>-making. Vietnam,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, recently established a legal framework<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultative relati<strong>on</strong>s between local-leveladministrators and the people they serve. Thisframework allows citizens to provide input andoversight in selected areas of local planning anddecisi<strong>on</strong>-making (ADB 2001c).Direct public participati<strong>on</strong> in regulatory policymakingdoes have its drawbacks, however. Bureaucraciesdesiring to introduce participati<strong>on</strong> shouldnot underestimate the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts it will possibly take.Issues that need attenti<strong>on</strong> are, am<strong>on</strong>g others, thedesign of the procedure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong>, the roleand authority citizens will have, and decisi<strong>on</strong>sabout representati<strong>on</strong>. For example, expectati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>both sides should be made clear from the beginning<strong>on</strong>. Decisi<strong>on</strong>-making processes may need tobe adjusted to the abilities of the n<strong>on</strong>-professi<strong>on</strong>alparticipants, who may be illiterate, inexperienced,or perhaps distrustful. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> provisi<strong>on</strong> of supportivefacilities could be necessary, or the involvement ofneutrals and experts who can help to process in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>,assess opti<strong>on</strong>s and facilitate negotiati<strong>on</strong>s.And even so, not all issues might be equally suited<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> participatory decisi<strong>on</strong>-making. Sometimes, anagency needs to be able to credibly commit not tochange its policy in resp<strong>on</strong>se to short-term publicpressure. It might be difficult, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, to encouragel<strong>on</strong>g-term investment in telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>sinfrastructure if investors know that rates willbe set in participatory fashi<strong>on</strong> by c<strong>on</strong>sumers: evenif c<strong>on</strong>sumers initially want to encourage investmentby promising a high rate of return, it may bedifficult <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> them to make that promise credible ifinvestors know that future rates will be set by anagency that is dominated by c<strong>on</strong>sumer interests(Levy and Spiller 1996, Henisz and Zelner 2001).A third strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improving access to bureaucraticjustice would emphasise re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that instituti<strong>on</strong>alisestandards of good governance andpromote public services morale. By giving bureaucraticmanagers sufficient means to offer theirsubordinates incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> good per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance, todiscipline bad per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance, and to reorganise outdatedpractices, bureaucratic organisati<strong>on</strong>s could51


e restructured in a way that reduces inefficiencyand waste and avoids inertia. This strategy may bepolitically sensitive, however. Civil service uni<strong>on</strong>sare very powerful in many developing countries,and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decades they and their members haveenjoyed almost complete tenure and salary protecti<strong>on</strong>s,little oversight, and few serious demands. Itmay there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e be risky <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the government to take<strong>on</strong> the civil service uni<strong>on</strong>s by proposing re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msthat would threaten the power or livelihoods ofthese uni<strong>on</strong>s and their members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, measuresenhancing bureaucratic justice and servicequality need to take into account the interestsof both the civil servants and their representingorganisati<strong>on</strong>s. Reorganisati<strong>on</strong>s might be moreacceptable if they are build <strong>on</strong> trust rather thandisapproval, motivate good practices rather thanpunish incompetence, stimulate learning fromfeedback rather than reprimand underper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance,and provide safeguards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> justified c<strong>on</strong>cernsregarding job security, wage guarantees andstatus. Approaching this delicate issue there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>erequires skilful politicians to enter into a c<strong>on</strong>sensus-buildingprocess with stakeholders and puttogether ‘package deals’ in which the existing civilservice establishment is given benefits in exchange<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> accepting re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that promote greaterbureaucratic productivity and efficiency. As analternative or complementary strategy, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merscould try to build a countervailing coaliti<strong>on</strong> thatwould push <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> bureaucratic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.A fourth type of strategy might promote decentralisati<strong>on</strong>,bureaucratic redundancy, or somedegree of privatisati<strong>on</strong> in service delivery, at least<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> certain types of service. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> advantages ofdecentralisati<strong>on</strong> are that it brings bureaucracy‘closer to the people’, may increase accountabilityand resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to local needs, and maypromote healthy competiti<strong>on</strong> between regi<strong>on</strong>s iflocal governments have input into bureaucraticgovernance within their jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s (Girishankaret al. 2002). Decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, however, mayincrease risks of corrupti<strong>on</strong> if it weakens centralizedoversight and depends <strong>on</strong> local individualsto make impartial decisi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> matters affectingtheir family, friends, and enemies (UNDP 2006).Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> may also reduce competence ifpowerful central bureaucracies are more likely toattract talented individuals.Bureaucratic redundancy — that is, having two ormore separate agencies or office provide the sameservice to the same target populati<strong>on</strong> — has threemain advantages. First, it reduces the likelihoodof incompetence or corrupti<strong>on</strong> by giving c<strong>on</strong>sumerswith a choice of provider (Shleifer and Vishny1993). Sec<strong>on</strong>d, if bureaucrats are rewarded atleast partially <strong>on</strong> the basis of demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theirservices, redundancy may lead to healthy competiti<strong>on</strong>between providers. Third, redundancymay facilitate experimentati<strong>on</strong> and innovati<strong>on</strong>.Bureaucratic redundancy also has costs, however.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first and most obvious is the extra budgetarycost of staffing two or more offices to provide essentiallythe same service. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d c<strong>on</strong>cernis that the existence of multiple providers mayblur lines of accountability and, if incentives areimproperly aligned, may encourage bureaucrats to‘let the other guy do the hard work’ (Ting 2003).Privatisati<strong>on</strong> of service delivery functi<strong>on</strong>s holdsthe promise of more efficient service delivery.C<strong>on</strong>sumer choice, value <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>ey, proximity tothe client and hands-<strong>on</strong> mentality are some appealingelements of this basic change towardsgovernance (Rhodes, 1997). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remix of bureaucraciesand markets c<strong>on</strong>taining the use ofbusiness principles and incentive structures isbelieved to motivate both the publicly and privatelyorganised service providers to adjust theservice delivery to the specific customers’ needs,resulting in an increase in effectiveness, resp<strong>on</strong>-52


siveness and transparency (Lane, 2000). However,privatisati<strong>on</strong> also risks undermining publicaccountability and creating more opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>corrupti<strong>on</strong>. Some high-profile scandals have d<strong>on</strong>eserious damage to the image of privatisati<strong>on</strong> as are<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategy. While these cauti<strong>on</strong>ary tales illustratethe dangers of ill c<strong>on</strong>ceived or badly managedprivatisati<strong>on</strong> ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts, they should not obscurethe fact that some privatisati<strong>on</strong> schemes cansubstantially increase the access of poor communitiesto vital government services. For example,water provisi<strong>on</strong> in Chile is heavily privatised, butsubject to a str<strong>on</strong>g regulatory system and coupledwith a subsidy programme to address equity c<strong>on</strong>cerns.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> scheme is widely viewed as effectivein providing clean water to poor communitiesefficiently and equitably (UNDP 2006).Administrative <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mIn additi<strong>on</strong> to general public administrati<strong>on</strong>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, there are a number of strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>improving access to bureaucratic justice thatemphasise a more direct role <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the legal andjudicial system. Administrative law may affectbureaucratic per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance in two distinct ways.First, legal rules en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced by courts may facilitateor en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce the public administrati<strong>on</strong> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mstrategies discussed above. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, courts andlitigants may take a more active role in overseeingthe activities of the public bureaucracy. While administrativelitigati<strong>on</strong> is <strong>on</strong>ly a small comp<strong>on</strong>entof a much larger set of governance instituti<strong>on</strong>s,and poor people are unlikely ever to be involveddirectly in a lawsuit against a bureaucratic agency,administrative law and litigati<strong>on</strong> may n<strong>on</strong>ethelesshave an important role to play in expandingaccess to bureaucratic justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. Thus,in this area of administrative law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, the issuesof access to bureaucratic justice and accessto legal justice overlap.<strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms to Facilitate Participati<strong>on</strong> andM<strong>on</strong>itoringThree major types of administrative law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mmay enhance the efficacy of external m<strong>on</strong>itoringmechanisms: freedom of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> (FOI) laws,‘impact statement’ requirements, and whistleblowerprotecti<strong>on</strong>s.FOI laws are meant to increase the transparencyby giving citizens entitlement to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>about bureaucratic rules, decisi<strong>on</strong>s, and practices.Traditi<strong>on</strong>ally, many governments resistedFOI legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> grounds of privacy or secrecy,and certain private interests may oppose FOI legislati<strong>on</strong>if these interests benefit from the abilityto manipulate a relatively opaque administrativeprocess <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their own benefit. Despite this, recogniti<strong>on</strong>of the benefits of FOI legislati<strong>on</strong> seems tobe <strong>on</strong> the rise: 65 countries currently have some<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of FOI legislati<strong>on</strong>, with most of those lawsenacted since 1990 (Kocaoglu and Figari 2006).FOI laws do have some important costs. Firstly,the traditi<strong>on</strong>al objecti<strong>on</strong>s based <strong>on</strong> privacy or secrecyc<strong>on</strong>cerns may have merit in some c<strong>on</strong>texts.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, certain exempti<strong>on</strong>s to FOI laws relatedto issues like nati<strong>on</strong>al security, <strong>on</strong>going courtproceedings, and pers<strong>on</strong>al or commercial privacymay be appropriate, though these exempti<strong>on</strong>sshould be narrowly drafted and c<strong>on</strong>strued. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly,in poor countries with weak bureaucraticcapacity, compliance with FOI requirements andresp<strong>on</strong>ding to FOI requests can be extremelycostly, and could end up paralysing the bureaucracy(Russell-Einhorn et al. 2002). This suggeststhat re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers should be careful not to simply liftFOI laws ‘off the shelf’ from wealthy countries;rather, FOI laws must be carefully tailored to theneeds and capacities of particular countries.Impact statement’ legislati<strong>on</strong> requires a governmentagency to provide a public report <strong>on</strong> the53


impact of a proposed acti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> some importantpublic value be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e the agency takes acti<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most comm<strong>on</strong> legislati<strong>on</strong> of this type is the‘envir<strong>on</strong>mental impact statement’ requirementpi<strong>on</strong>eered by the U.S. Nati<strong>on</strong>al Envir<strong>on</strong>mentalPolicy Act of 1970 and adopted by numerousother countries and some internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s.Though the specifics of these laws vary,they all require that agencies prepare a report <strong>on</strong>the impact of major proposed acti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>mentalquality. Other types of impact statementrequirements have also been proposed, and afew have been implemented, though the envir<strong>on</strong>mentalimpact statement is still by far the mostcomm<strong>on</strong> versi<strong>on</strong> of this strategy. One approachthat might be worth c<strong>on</strong>sidering is the use of a‘poverty impact statement’ that would requireagencies, after c<strong>on</strong>sulting the poor community, toproduce a report <strong>on</strong> how their initiatives are likelyto affect the poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main advantages of impactstatement laws are, first, that they increasepublic accountability and the efficacy of externaloversight by disclosing potential adverse effectsof agency acti<strong>on</strong>, and, sec<strong>on</strong>d, that they mayalter the agency’s own internal decisi<strong>on</strong>-makingprocess by drawing attenti<strong>on</strong> to issues that mightotherwise be ignored or neglected. However, impactstatement requirements, like FOI legislati<strong>on</strong>,can be burdensome, especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> under-fundedor low-capacity agencies. Saddling bureaucracieswith too many impact statement requirementsmay induce ‘paralysis by analysis’. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> appropriatebalance between these competing interestscannot be resolved in abstract or general terms.Whistleblower protecti<strong>on</strong> statutes are a third<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of administrative law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m that seeks toimprove transparency and political accountability.Without credible protecti<strong>on</strong>s, individuals withina bureaucratic organisati<strong>on</strong> who learn about corrupti<strong>on</strong>or other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of malfeasance will be reluctantto come <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward because they fear retaliati<strong>on</strong>.Effective whistleblower protecti<strong>on</strong> statutestypically enable individuals to make complaintsan<strong>on</strong>ymously or c<strong>on</strong>fidentially, imposing seriouscivil and criminal penalties <strong>on</strong> those who retaliateagainst whistleblowers, and (sometimes) givingpotential whistleblowers a financial incentive tocome <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward either by offering them a set ‘bounty’<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> useful in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> or by offering them apercentage of any m<strong>on</strong>ey the government recoversfrom wr<strong>on</strong>gdoers as a result of the whistleblower’sreport. Whistleblower protecti<strong>on</strong> statutes may notbe effective in redressing endemic or high-levelcorrupti<strong>on</strong>, especially when the en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement ofthe laws is unreliable, but these statutes mayn<strong>on</strong>etheless be effective and important elementsof a broader anti-corrupti<strong>on</strong> strategy.Judicial Review of Administrative Decisi<strong>on</strong>sFOI legislati<strong>on</strong>, impact statement laws, andwhistleblower protecti<strong>on</strong> statutes are all legalmechanisms through which courts en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce rulesthat enable other actors — NGOs, politicians, andthe media — to m<strong>on</strong>itor bureaucratic per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mancemore effectively. Thus, increasing the abilityof individuals and groups to make sure these lawsare en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced may improve poor people’s access tobureaucratic justice.Litigati<strong>on</strong> and judicial instituti<strong>on</strong>s may also play amore direct role in ensuring bureaucratic accountability.Such litigati<strong>on</strong> can take two main <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.First, some litigants pursue what might be termed‘oversight’ litigati<strong>on</strong>. Individuals who believe thata government agency has taken, or is about totake, some illegal acti<strong>on</strong> that adversely affectstheir interests may file a legal challenge. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> judiciarythen assumes the role of public m<strong>on</strong>itor,ensuring that the agency has acted lawfully.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of litigati<strong>on</strong> is so-called ‘publicinterest litigati<strong>on</strong>’ (PIL). Citizen groups typically54


ing PIL suits to effect broader legal change orinstituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. PIL has played a significantrole in the strategy of social re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m movementsin South Asia and South Africa in particular, andit is increasingly comm<strong>on</strong> in other parts of theworld as well (NCLEP India 2007, Dembrowski2000, Gloppen 2005, Hershkoff and McCrutche<strong>on</strong>2000). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> distincti<strong>on</strong> between oversightlitigati<strong>on</strong> and PIL is more a matter of degree thana difference in kind. Oversight litigati<strong>on</strong> moreclosely resembles a traditi<strong>on</strong>al lawsuit alleging aprivate injury to a legally protected interest, whilePIL seeks to involve the judiciary in a more overtlylaw-making or re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mist role, but in practicemany oversight suits seek instituti<strong>on</strong>al changes,and much PIL is directed toward the redress ofwidely-shared private grievances against bureaucraticinstituti<strong>on</strong>s.Litigati<strong>on</strong> is not the most desirable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of improvingadministrative accountability and bureaucraticjustice. In the first place, any strategy thatrelies <strong>on</strong> litigati<strong>on</strong> and judicial review is likelyto be expensive and time-c<strong>on</strong>suming. ‘Retail’administrative lawsuits may also put an enormousburden <strong>on</strong> the court system. For example,in many Latin American countries citizens whobelieve they have been wr<strong>on</strong>gly denied a governmentbenefit can file an amparo claim directlyin the civil courts, thereby circumventing the administrativereview process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se amparo claimsclog the courts, and because they are focused<strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> the individual claim they tend not to addressthe root cause of bureaucratic failure.Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, courts may lack the expertise neededto understand the complex, technical issues thatoften arise in administrative law or instituti<strong>on</strong>alre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m cases. Judges, however, may overestimatetheir own competence in such matters. Somecountries have attempted to address this problemby establishing specialised administrative courts,but even in these cases judges are at a comparativedisadvantage compared to other instituti<strong>on</strong>swhen c<strong>on</strong>sidering issues of bureaucratic instituti<strong>on</strong>aldesign.Finally, some observers have raised the c<strong>on</strong>cernthat well-intenti<strong>on</strong>ed re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers, especially thosewith elite legal backgrounds, may be seducedby the appeal of litigati<strong>on</strong> as a vehicle of socialchange and pursue this strategy at the expenseof more valuable — but less visible and exciting— political organisati<strong>on</strong>, lobbying, and educati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> three c<strong>on</strong>cerns cited are all valid, and litigati<strong>on</strong>should generally not be the first line ofdefence (or offence) in dealing with an abusive,unaccountable, or underper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming bureaucracy.Nevertheless, having available litigati<strong>on</strong> as aweap<strong>on</strong> of last resort may be vital in making theother mechanisms of bureaucratic justice functi<strong>on</strong>effectively. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> principles that should applyto both to administrative oversight litigati<strong>on</strong>and to PIL are the same as those discussed inthe c<strong>on</strong>text of access to legal justice generally:re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers should work to eliminate failures inthe market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal services and litigati<strong>on</strong>, andestablish instituti<strong>on</strong>s that allocate scarce judicialresources to the cases where judicial interventi<strong>on</strong>is most necessary and appropriate. Thus, desirableapproaches may include broadening rulesof standing, adopting <strong>on</strong>e-way fee-shifting rules,facilitating representative or collective lawsuits,and targeting scarce legal aid resources at casesthat affect large numbers of people, while at thesame time re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer should provide more opti<strong>on</strong>sand resources <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-judicial relief of administrativedisputes, and should require exhausti<strong>on</strong>of administrative remedies as a prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>judicial review.55


5. C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s andRecommendati<strong>on</strong>sIn order to escape the poverty trap, poor peopleneed a legal system that enables them to realisethe full value of their physical and humancapital. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> three substantive cornerst<strong>on</strong>es ofthe legal empowerment agenda are property law,labour law, and law <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> small business. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mof the substantive law, however necessary, wouldnot be sufficient to achieve true legal empowerment.For the legal system to play a role inempowering the poor to lift themselves out ofpoverty, they need more than laws c<strong>on</strong>ferring theappropriate mix of rights, powers, privileges, andimmunities; they also need a legal and judicialsystem that can make these legal entitlementspractical and meaningful. Empowering the poorand disadvantaged to seek remedies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> injusticerequires ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to develop and/or strengthen linkagesbetween <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal structures andto counter biases inherent in both systems. Ourworking group has examined the issues involvedand has developed guidelines to provide ways ofimproving access to justice.Summarising our main c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s, we stressthat access to justice requires granting allpeople an individual identity (see Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 ofthis chapter), and that realising this goal requires:• Addressing the lack of bureaucratic capacityin states’ identity registrati<strong>on</strong> systems byeliminating user fees, supporting outreach,working through n<strong>on</strong>-governmental organisati<strong>on</strong>s,and bundling registrati<strong>on</strong> services withother social services or traditi<strong>on</strong>al practicesand creating <strong>on</strong>e stop shops.• Counteracting politically-motivated legal exclusi<strong>on</strong>by a combinati<strong>on</strong> of facilitati<strong>on</strong> ofpolitical dialogue, legislative re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, internati<strong>on</strong>alattenti<strong>on</strong>, engaging nati<strong>on</strong>al humanrights machineries, stakeholder c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s,and community involvement.• Creating incentives to register <strong>on</strong>e’s legal identitywith the state by providing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>,working through trustworthy local intermediaries,and minimising the adverse c<strong>on</strong>sequencesof <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong>.In Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 of this chapter, we identified fourstrategies to improve access to justice, taking thejustifiable problems of the poor as starting points.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y build <strong>on</strong> the opti<strong>on</strong>s poor people have availableto address these problems and to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cetheir rights: sp<strong>on</strong>taneous ordering mechanisms,in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal, faith-based and customary justice, aswell as the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> comm<strong>on</strong> aimof these strategies is to lower costs that may beinvolved and increase justness and fairness of theoutcomes poor people may obtain. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se strategieshave proven their value in practice, or seemparticularly promising in the light of a theoreticalframework that emphasises reducti<strong>on</strong> of transacti<strong>on</strong>costs and remedying market failure:• Empowering the poor through improved disseminati<strong>on</strong>of legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>of peer groups (self-help strategies). This canbe d<strong>on</strong>e by strengthening in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>-sharingnetworks across c<strong>on</strong>sumer groups and organisati<strong>on</strong>s,by using in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> technology, n<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallegal educati<strong>on</strong> and media campaigns,tailored to the target populati<strong>on</strong> and theirproblems.• Broadening the scope of legal services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepoor, in several directi<strong>on</strong>s: an orientati<strong>on</strong> towardsempowerment, coaching and learning;lower cost delivery-models (through paralegals,or otherwise); bundling with other services(health care, banking, insurance) and intro-56


ducing the c<strong>on</strong>cept of <strong>on</strong>e stop shop; use ofthe methods and skills of alternative disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong>, mediati<strong>on</strong> and arbitrati<strong>on</strong>; and legalaid services that are capable of assistancewith the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system as well as the statesystem. Moreover, the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal servicesshould gradually be liberalised by reducingregulatory entry barriers (such as ‘unauthorisedpractice of law’ restricti<strong>on</strong>) <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> serviceproviders, including n<strong>on</strong>-lawyers, who are interestedin offering legal services to the poor.Scarce legal aid resources should be targetedto cases where the legal claim produces publicgoods (such as general deterrence or legalre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m) and to situati<strong>on</strong>s with very high stakes<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the individual (such as criminal defence).• Reducing aggregate legal transacti<strong>on</strong> costs byadopting a combinati<strong>on</strong> of legal simplificati<strong>on</strong>and standardisati<strong>on</strong> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, expanded opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> representative or aggregate legalclaims, and improving the climate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fair settlementsin the shadow of law, by ensuring acredible threat of a neutral interventi<strong>on</strong>.• Combining <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or tacit recogniti<strong>on</strong> of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice system with educati<strong>on</strong> andawareness campaigns that promote evoluti<strong>on</strong>of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal state system, targeted c<strong>on</strong>straints<strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system (in particularlimits <strong>on</strong> practices that perpetuate the subordinati<strong>on</strong>of women), and appropriately structuringthe relati<strong>on</strong>ship between state and n<strong>on</strong>statesystems so that the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system canprovide an efficient means of resolving privatedisputes, but people are able to use the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsystem when crime and fundamental publicvalues are implicated.and obtain necessary services, access to justicere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m may require not <strong>on</strong>ly improving access toadjudicative justice, but also improving access tobureaucratic justice (discussed in Secti<strong>on</strong> 4). Addressingthe failures of the bureaucratic systemmay entail:• Public administrati<strong>on</strong> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, includingre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that improve external m<strong>on</strong>itoringand also structural re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms (such as improvingbureaucratic adjudicati<strong>on</strong> and grievanceprocedures, expanding public participati<strong>on</strong>in administrative decisi<strong>on</strong>-making, pursuingcivil service re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m to expand opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance incentives in government administrati<strong>on</strong>,and increasing decentralisati<strong>on</strong> andredundancy in bureaucratic service provisi<strong>on</strong>to improve efficiency and combat corrupti<strong>on</strong>.• Administrative law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, including appropriately-tailoredexpansi<strong>on</strong>s of freedom ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> laws, impact statement requirements,and whistleblower protecti<strong>on</strong>s, as wellas appropriate but limited judicial review ofadministrative acti<strong>on</strong>.Because many poor people have to rely <strong>on</strong> accessto the (local) government hierarchy rather thanthe adjudicative system to resolve their disputes57


Chapter 1 Endnotes1 Excellent recent reports prepared by the Asian Development Bank(ADB) (2004, 2005, 2007), UNICEF (2002, 2005), and the Inter-AmericanDevelopment Bank (IADB) (2006) <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the basis of much of thematerial in this secti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se organisati<strong>on</strong>s have taken an importantleadership role by bringing this problem to the attenti<strong>on</strong> of the internati<strong>on</strong>alcommunity - gathering vital in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the nature andscope of the problem and developing possible strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.2 For example, the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Covenant <strong>on</strong> Civil and PoliticalRights, Arts. 16 and 24; Internati<strong>on</strong>al Covenant <strong>on</strong> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic, Social,and Cultural Rights, Arts. 6 and 13; C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the Rights of theChild, Arts. 7—8; Internati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the Protecti<strong>on</strong> of theRights of All Migrant <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers, Art. 9; C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the Eliminati<strong>on</strong> ofAll Forms of Discriminati<strong>on</strong> Against Women, Arts. 7—9; American C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> Human Rights, Art. 20; European C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Nati<strong>on</strong>ality,Art. 6; African Charter <strong>on</strong> the Rights and Welfare of the Child, Arts. 6and 11.3 Sources discussing these and other groups include Lynch and Ali(2006), Lynch (2005), Amnesty Internati<strong>on</strong>al (2005), Sokoloff (2006),Refugees Internati<strong>on</strong>al (2006), Kalvaitis (1998), and Adam (2006).4 Describing this barrier as a ‘transacti<strong>on</strong> cost’ is not meant totrivialise the feelings of cultural and social exclusi<strong>on</strong> this linguisticbarrier may also engender. This phenomen<strong>on</strong> may create a type ofpsychological cost to using the legal system that is as signifi cant, inpractical terms, as the ec<strong>on</strong>omic cost.5 It is worth noting, however, that the issue of linguistic barriers toaccess, like the issue of legal identity discussed earlier, may implicateserious political c<strong>on</strong>fl icts. Sometimes linguistic barriers to access arisebecause of government policies designed specifi cally to disadvantageparticular ethnic groups, or to advantage the wealthy relative to thepoor. Thus, even if the fi nancial costs of dealing with this particularobstacle may be relatively low, the political costs may be greater.6 Much of this discussi<strong>on</strong> is based <strong>on</strong> an excellent recent reportprepared by Ewa Wojkowska (2006) of the UNDP’s Oslo GovernanceCentre.Chapter 1 BibliographyAdam, A.H. 2006. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nubians and Statelessness: History in Defi ningModern Lives, available at http://www.justiceinitiative.org/statelessness_meeting.Afroz, T. 2006. ‘Access to <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Bangladesh Perspective.’ availableat http://www.adb.org/Documents/Books/Strengthening-Criminal-Justice-system/chap04.Anders<strong>on</strong>, M.2003. Access to Justice and <strong>Legal</strong> Process: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong>Instituti<strong>on</strong>s Resp<strong>on</strong>sive to Poor People in LDCs (IDS <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ingPaper 178, Feb. 2003).Ardaya, G. and G. Sierra.2002. Toward an Inclusive Electi<strong>on</strong>s Process:Final Report of Pro-Citizens’ Participati<strong>on</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sortium.UKDepartment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development. La Paz, Bolivia.Amnesty Internati<strong>on</strong>al.2005. Myanmar: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rohingya Minority: FundamentalRights Denied. available at: http://www.justiceinitiative.org/statelessness_meeting.Asian Development Bank (ADB). 2001a. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Policy Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m at theAsian Development Bank 2000. vol. 2, available at http://www.asianlii.org/asia/other/ADBLPRes/2001/2.pdf._____. 2001b. Report and Recommendati<strong>on</strong> of the President to theBoard of Directors <strong>on</strong> Proposed and Technical AssistanceGrant to the Islamic Republic of Pakistan <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Access toJustice Programme, available at http://www.adb.org/Documents/RRPS/PAK/rrp_32023.pdf._____. (ADB) 2001c. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment: Advancing Good Governanceand Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>, 2000, available at http://www.adb.org/Documents/Others/<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>_ADB/lpr_2001_Part_2.pdf._____. 2002. Technical Assistance Completi<strong>on</strong> Report — Disseminating<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s and Strengthening the <strong>Legal</strong> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> System,TA 3238-TAJ, available at http://www.adb.org/Documents/TACRs/TAJ/tacr_taj_3238.pdf._____. 2004., Technical Assistance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Establishing <strong>Legal</strong> Identity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Social Inclusi<strong>on</strong>, R188-04 (Oct. 4, 2004)._____. 2005. Incepti<strong>on</strong> Report: Establishing <strong>Legal</strong> Identity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> SocialInclusi<strong>on</strong>, RETA No. 6188 Aug.10, 2005)._____. 2007. <strong>Legal</strong> Identity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Inclusive Development (CarolineVandanabeele and Christine V. Lao, eds.).Axworthy, L. 2007. Quoted in ‘Toward C<strong>on</strong>sensus.’ <strong>Legal</strong> EmpowermentQuarterly. July 2007.p. 2.Barendrecht, M. and P. van Nispen, Micro-justice (Internati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>Legal</strong>Alliances), available at http://www.intall.org/documents/PaperMicrojustice0704.pdf.Bart<strong>on</strong>, B. 2001. ‘Why Do We Regulate <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>yers?: An Ec<strong>on</strong>omicAnalysis of the Justifi cati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Entry and C<strong>on</strong>ductRegulati<strong>on</strong>.’Ariz<strong>on</strong>a State <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Journal 33:429-490.Bloom, A.2006. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics of Civil Justice: From Justice to GlobalPeace: A (Brief) Genealogy of the Class Acti<strong>on</strong> Crisis.’Loyolaof Los Angeles <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review. 39:719.Bolt<strong>on</strong>, P. and M. Dewatrip<strong>on</strong>t.2005. C<strong>on</strong>tract <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory. Cambridge andL<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: MIT Press.Bueno de Mesquita, E. and M. Stephens<strong>on</strong>. 2007. ‘Regulatory QualityUnder Imperfect Oversight.’ American Political ScienceReview. 101(3):605-620.58


Buscaglia, E. and T. Ulen. 1997. ‘A Quantitative Assessment of theEffi ciency of the Judicial Sector in Latin America.’ Internati<strong>on</strong>alReview of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics. 17:275.Cantrell, D. 2004. ‘Deborah L. Rhode’s Access to Justice: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Obligati<strong>on</strong>of <strong>Legal</strong> Aid <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>yers To Champi<strong>on</strong> Practice by N<strong>on</strong>lawyers.’Fordham <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review. 73:883.Capper, D. 2003. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>tingency <strong>Legal</strong> Aid Fund: A Third Way toFinance Pers<strong>on</strong>al Injury Litigati<strong>on</strong>.’ Journal of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> andSociety. 30(1):66-83.Carothers, T. 2003: ‘Promoting the Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Abroad: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Problem ofKnowledge.’ Carnegie Endowment WOrking Paper No. 34.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C. January 2003Centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Applied <strong>Legal</strong> Studies.2002. Final Report <strong>on</strong> Gender, Citizenshipand Governance Project.Damazo, J. 2006. Registering a New Sense of Identity, available athttp://www.adb.org/media/Articles/2006/11077-Cambodialegal-identity/.Dembowski, H. 2000. Taking the State to Court: Public Interest Litigati<strong>on</strong>and the Public Sphere in India.Domberger, S. and A. Sherr.1989. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Impact of Competiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Pricingand Quality of <strong>Legal</strong> Services.’ Internati<strong>on</strong>al Review of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics. 9:41-56.Dun<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d, C. 2002.’Building Better Lives: Sustainable Integrati<strong>on</strong> ofMicro-fi nance with Educati<strong>on</strong> in Child Survival, ReproductiveHealth, and HIV/AIDS Preventi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poorest Entrepreneurs.’In: Daley-Harris, S. ed., Pathways Out of Poverty.Bloomfi eld, C<strong>on</strong>n: Kumarian Press, Inc.Faundez, J. 2006. ‘Should Justice Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Projects Take N<strong>on</strong>-State JusticeSystems Seriously? Perspectives from Latin America.’in <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank <strong>Legal</strong> Review: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Equity, and Development.Galanter, M. 1976., ‘Delivering <strong>Legal</strong>ity: Some Proposals <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Directi<strong>on</strong>of Research.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Society Review. 11:225-246._____. M. 1974. ‘Why the ‘Haves’ Come Out Ahead: Speculati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>the Limits of <strong>Legal</strong> Change.’<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Society Review. 9:95-160.Gidi, A. 2003. ‘Class Acti<strong>on</strong>s in Brazil — A Model <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Civil <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>Countries.’American Journal of Comparative <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>. 51:311-.Girishankar, N. et al. 2002. ‘Governance,’ in Klugman, J., ed., A Sourcebook<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong> Strategies, available at http://poverty2.<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um<strong>on</strong>e.com/fi les/4105_cahp8.pdf.Gloppen, S. 2005.,Public Interest Litigati<strong>on</strong>, Social Rights and SocialPolicy, available at http://siteresources.worldbank.org/IN-TRANETSOCIALDEVELOPMENT/Resources/Gloppen.rev.3. pdf.Golub, S. 2000. ‘Bey<strong>on</strong>d the Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Orthodoxy: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> EmpowermentAlternative.’ Carnegie Endowment <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing PaperNo. 41. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C. October 2003._____. 2003. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment Alternative, in T. Carothers ed.,Promoting the Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Abroad, In Search of Knowledge._____. 2004., Forging the Future: Engaging <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Students andYoung <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>yers in Public Service, Human Rights, andPoverty Alleviati<strong>on</strong> (Open Society Justice Initiative IssuesPaper), available at http://www.justiceinitiative.org/db/resource2?res_id=101449._____. ‘Combating Corrupti<strong>on</strong> in N<strong>on</strong>-judicial Justice Systems.’ inGlobal Corrupti<strong>on</strong> Report 2007. Transparency Internati<strong>on</strong>al(L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Pluto Press, 2007).Grajzl, P. and P. Murrell. 2006. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>yers and Politicians: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Impactof Organised <strong>Legal</strong> Professi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.’C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy.17(4):251-276.Hammergren, L. 2007. Access to Justice: <strong>Legal</strong> Assistance, SpecialCourts, ADR, and Bey<strong>on</strong>d.Hay, J., A. Shleifer and R. Vishny.1996. ‘Toward a <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory of <strong>Legal</strong> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.’European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review. 40:559-567.Henisz, W. and B. Zelner.2001. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s Investment.’ Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics andManagement Strategy 10(1):123-147.Hershkoff, H. and A. McCutche<strong>on</strong>.2000. ‘Public Interest Litigati<strong>on</strong>:An Internati<strong>on</strong>al Perspective,’ in Many Roads to Justice:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>-Related <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> of Foundati<strong>on</strong> Grantees Around theWorld. McClym<strong>on</strong>t, M. and S. Golub, eds. New York: FordFoundati<strong>on</strong>.Hoffman, M., P. Rubin and J. Shepherd.2005. ‘An Empirical Studyof Public Defender Effectiveness: Self-Selecti<strong>on</strong> by the‘Marginally Indigent’.’ Ohio State Journal of Criminal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>3:223-255.Huber, J. and N. McCarty. 2004. ‘Bureaucratic Capacity, Delegati<strong>on</strong>,and Political Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.’ American Political Science Review.98(3):481-494.Inter-American Development Bank (IADB).2006. Hidden in Plain Sight:Undocumented Citizens in Latin America. Ideas <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Developmentin the Americas 1 (Jan.-Apr. 2006).Kalvaitis, R. 1998. ‘Citizenship and Nati<strong>on</strong>al Identity in the BalticStates.’ Bost<strong>on</strong> University Internati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Journal.16:231.Kennedy, A.2007. Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> (LEP <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper).Killian, M. 2003. ‘Alternatives to Public Provisi<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role of <strong>Legal</strong>Expenses Insurance in Broadening Access to Justice: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>German Experience.’ Journal of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Society. 30(1):31-48.Kocaoglu, N. and A. Figari. 2006. Using the Right to In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> as anAnti-Corrupti<strong>on</strong> Tool. (Transparency Internati<strong>on</strong>al), availableat http://www.transparentnost.org.yu/aktivnosti/slobodan_pristup_inf/TI2006_europe_access_in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.pdf.Kritzer, H. 1997. ‘Rethinking Barriers to <strong>Legal</strong> Practice.’ Judicature81(3):100-103._____. 2004. Risks, Reputati<strong>on</strong>s, and Rewards: C<strong>on</strong>tingency Fee<strong>Legal</strong> Practice in the United States.Laczo, M. 2003. ‘Deprived of an Individual Identity: Citizenship andWomen in Nepal.’Gender and Development. 11(3):76-82.Landes, W. and R. Posner. 1979. ‘Adjudicati<strong>on</strong> as a Private Good.’Journal of <strong>Legal</strong> Studies 8:235-284.Lane, Jan-Erik. 2000. New Public Management. New York: Routledge.Levy, B. and P. Spiller. 1996. Regulati<strong>on</strong>s, Instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and Commitment:A Comparative Analysis of Telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>sRegulati<strong>on</strong>. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Lin, Zixin. 2006. Thailand: Faster Citizenship <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Hilltribes Pushed,available at http://www.newsmek<strong>on</strong>g.org/thailand_faster_citizenship_<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>_hilltribes_pushed.59


Lopez-de-Silanes, F. 2002. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Politics of <strong>Legal</strong> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m (U.N. C<strong>on</strong>ference<strong>on</strong> Trade and Development. G-24 Discussi<strong>on</strong> PaperSeries No. 17), available at http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/pogdsmdpbg24d17.en.pdf.Lynch, M. 2005. ‘Lives <strong>on</strong> Hold: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Human Cost of Statelessness.’Refugees Internati<strong>on</strong>al 23.Lynch, M. and P. Ali. 2006. Buried Alive: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Kurds in Syria, RefugeesInternati<strong>on</strong>al. Jan. 2006.MacCormack, D.N. and R. Summers eds. 1991. Interpreting Statutes: AComparative Study._____. 1997. Interpreting Precedent: A Comparative Study.Maru, V. 2006. ‘Between <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Society: Paralegals and the Provisi<strong>on</strong>of Justice Services in Sierra Le<strong>on</strong>e and Worldwide.’YaleJournal of Internati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>. 31:427-476.McClym<strong>on</strong>t, M. and S. Golub, eds . 2000. Many Roads to Justice: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>-Related <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> of Ford Foundati<strong>on</strong>: Grantees Around theWorld. Ford Foundati<strong>on</strong>. 2000.McQuoid-Mas<strong>on</strong>, D.2000. “<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Delivery of Civil <strong>Legal</strong> Aid Servicesin South Africa.’ Fordham Internati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Journal. 24:S111-S142.Men<strong>on</strong>, N.R.M. 2007..’<strong>Legal</strong> Educati<strong>on</strong> and Training in Bangladesh.’In:Strengthening the CriminalJustice System . Asian DevelopmentBank.Messick, R. 1999. Judicial ‘Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Development: ASurvey of the Issues.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank Research Observer.14(1):117-136.Michels<strong>on</strong>, E. 2007. ‘Climbing the Dispute Pagoda: Grievances andAppeals to the Offi cial Justice System in Rural China.’American Sociological Review. 72,2:459—485, 2007.Millennium Promise. 2007. ‘Millennium Villages: A Revoluti<strong>on</strong> Is Possible.’available at http://www.millenniumpromise.org/site/PageServer?pagename=mv_main.Murphy, K., A. Shleifer and R. Vishny.1991.’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Allocati<strong>on</strong> of Talent:Implicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Growth.’ Quarterly Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics.106(2):503-530.Narayan, D. 2002.Empowerment and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>: A Sourcebook.________. 2005. Measuring Empowerment; Cross Disciplinary Perspectives,IBRD/World Bank.Nati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor (NCLEP)Ethiopia, Paper prepared <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice.2007._____. India, Paper prepared <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice. 2007._____. Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, Paper prepared <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice.2007._____. Kenya, Paper prepared <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice.2007._____. Pakistan, Paper prepared <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice.2007._____. Philippines, Paper prepared <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice.2007._____. Tanzania, Paper prepared <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice. 2007._____. Uganda, Paper prepared <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice.2007.Open Society Institute . 2004. ‘Justice Initiatives: <strong>Legal</strong> Aid Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mand Access to Justice.’ Feb. 2004, available at http://www.soros.org/resources/articles_publicati<strong>on</strong>s/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/justice_20040225/justice_initiatives_20040225_2.pdfPaldi, B. 2006. ‘A Step Towards Peace.’ ACE Electoral KnowledgeNetwork, available at http://aceproject.org/today/featurearticles/a-step-towards-peace.Posner, R. 1998. Creating a <strong>Legal</strong> Framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Development.World Bank Research Observer 13:1-11.Refugees Internati<strong>on</strong>al, Stateless Biharis in Bangladesh: A HumanitarianNightmare, available at http://www.refugeesinternati<strong>on</strong>al.org/c<strong>on</strong>tent/article/detail/4666/.Regan, F. 2003. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swedish <strong>Legal</strong> Services Policy Remix: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Shiftfrom Public <strong>Legal</strong> Aid to Private <strong>Legal</strong> Expense Insurance.’Journal of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Society. 30(1):49-65.Rhode, D. 2000. In the Interest of Justice: Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the legal professi<strong>on</strong>.New York: Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d University Press._____. 2004. Access to Justice. New York: Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d University Press._____. Rhodes, R.A.W. 1997. Understanding Governance; Policy Networks,Governance,Refl exivity and Accountability. Buckingham, Philadelphia: Open UniversityPress.Russell-Einhorn, M. et al. 2002. ‘Strengthening Access to In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>and Public Participati<strong>on</strong> inTransiti<strong>on</strong> Countries — Latviaas a Case Study in Administrative <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.’ Administrative<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review. 54:459-.Schwartz, A., and L. Wilde.1979. ‘Intervening in Markets <strong>on</strong> the Basisof Imperfect In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>: A <strong>Legal</strong> and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Analysis.’University of Pennsylvania <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review. 127:630-.Shavell, S. 1995. ‘Alternative Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong>: An Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Analysis.’Journal of <strong>Legal</strong> Studies. 24:1-28._____. 1997. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fundamental Divergence Between the Private andthe Social Motive to Use the <strong>Legal</strong> System.’ Journal of <strong>Legal</strong>Studies. 26:575-612._____. 1982. ‘Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical Analysis UnderAlternative Methods <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Allocati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Legal</strong> Costs.’Journal of <strong>Legal</strong> Studies. 11(1):55-81.Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny.1993. ‘Corrupti<strong>on</strong>.’ Quarterly Journal ofEc<strong>on</strong>omics 108(3):599-617.Sokoloff, C. 2006. Denial of Citizenship: A Challenge to Human Security.Spaulding, N.2004. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Luxury of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Codifi cati<strong>on</strong> Movementand the Right to Counsel.’ Fordham <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review 73:983-.Thomas, G. and A. Shrestha. 1998. Breaking New Ground: A Case Studyof Women’s Empowerment in Nepal, Women’s EmpowermentProgramme (USAID/Nepal)Ting, M.2003. ‘A Strategic <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory of Bureaucratic Redundancy.’ AmericanJournal of Political Science. 47(2):274-292.Tsikata, D. 2003. ‘Securing Women’s Interests Within Land TenureRe<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms: Recent Debates in Tanzania.’ Journal of AgrarianChange. 3:149-183.UNICEF. 2006. Birth Registrati<strong>on</strong> in Bangladesh, available at http://www.unicef.org/bangladesh/Birth_Registrati<strong>on</strong>_in_Bangladesh.pdf._____. 2005. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘Rights’ Start to Life: A Statistical Analysis of BirthRegistrati<strong>on</strong>, available at http://www.childinfo.org/areas/birthregistrati<strong>on</strong>/docs/Full%20text%20English.pdf.______. 2003. Birth Registrati<strong>on</strong>, available at http://www.unicef.org/southafrica/protecti<strong>on</strong>_761.html.______. 2002. ‘Birth Registrati<strong>on</strong>: Right from the Start.’ InnocentiDigest 9:1.60


United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Development Programme (UNDP). 2005. Programming<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Justice: Access <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> All; A Human Rights-Based Approachto Access to Justice, available at http://regi<strong>on</strong>alcenterbankok.undp.or.th/practices/governance/a2j/tools/index1.htm._____. 2006. U.N. Human Development Report 2006 — Bey<strong>on</strong>dScarcity: Power, Poverty, and the Global Water Crisis._____. 2007. Human Security in Bangladesh: In Search of Justice andDignity._____. (UNDP Ind<strong>on</strong>esia.) 2007 Justice For All? — An Assessment ofAccess to Justice in Five Provinces of Ind<strong>on</strong>esia.United States Agency <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development (USAID).2002.Achievements in Building and Maintaining the Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>:MSI’s Studies in LAC, EandE, AFR, and ANE. Occasi<strong>on</strong>alPaper Series by USAID. Nov. 2002, available at http://www.usaid.gov/our_work/democracy_and_governance/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/pdfs/pnacr220.pdf._____. 2006. Administrative <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Procedural Systems (ALPS)Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in Bosnia and Herzegovina, 3rd Annual Report,available at http://www.usaid.ba/Assessments/Admin%20<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>%20Assessments/IRIS_ALPS%202005%20Annual%20Report.doc.Van Rooij, B. 2007. Bringing Justice to the Poor: Bottom-up <strong>Legal</strong>Development Cooperati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing paper available athttp://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTJUSFORPOOR/Resources/VanRooijBringingJusticetothePoor.pdfVigoda, E. 2002. ‘From Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to Collaborati<strong>on</strong>: Governance,Citizens, and the Next Generati<strong>on</strong> of Public Administrati<strong>on</strong>.’Public Administrati<strong>on</strong> Review. 62: 527-538.Wojkowska, E. 2006. Doing Justice: How In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Justice Systems CanC<strong>on</strong>tribute (UNDP, Oslo Governance Centre), available athttp://www.undp.org/oslocentre/docs07/DoingJusticeEwa-Wojkowska130307.pdf.World Bank. 2007. ‘Promoting the Right of Egyptian Woman To Claim<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir Identity and <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir Futures.’ Development MarketplaceProject Stories. Available at http://go.worldbank.org/3DKFL6QT90._____. 1997. ‘Restraining Arbitrary State Acti<strong>on</strong> and Corrupti<strong>on</strong>.’ In:World Development Report. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.: Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d UniversityPress.Yeazell, S. 2006, ‘Socializing <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Privatizing <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, M<strong>on</strong>opolizing<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Accessing <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>.’ Loyola of Los Angeles <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review.39(2):691-717.61


ChapterTWOEmpowering thePoor ThroughProperty Rights63


EXECUTIVE SUMMARYProperty Rights are Human Rights‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Every<strong>on</strong>e</str<strong>on</strong>g> has the right to own property al<strong>on</strong>e as well as in associati<strong>on</strong> with others … .No <strong>on</strong>e shall be arbitrarily deprived of his property.’ 1Property rights must be understood as afundamental human right. 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> body andmind are the first and most immediateproperty of pers<strong>on</strong>s and thus respect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thisproperty is related to the respect of the integrityof the individual. 3 Throughout history the ideaof human rights has developed in close associati<strong>on</strong>with the idea of private property rights. 4Early defenders of human rights c<strong>on</strong>sideredproperty rights as important as freedom of religi<strong>on</strong>and freedom of speech. But the majority ofthe world’s populati<strong>on</strong> does not have adequateaccess to secure property rights, and their realisati<strong>on</strong>remains an arena <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> social and politicalc<strong>on</strong>testati<strong>on</strong>.Absence of Property Rights andPoverty<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> absence or insecurity of property rights is acentral and ubiquitous cause of poverty, not <strong>on</strong>lyin the very poorest states, but also in middleincomecountries such as Brazil, Russia, Indiaand China. 5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> relati<strong>on</strong>ship between absence ofproperty rights and poverty is moving from argumentand anecdote to comparative analysis andmeasurement. Secure property rights facilitateec<strong>on</strong>omic transacti<strong>on</strong>s, ensure efficient and sustainableresource use, allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the evoluti<strong>on</strong> ofeffective credit markets, improve business climateand investment opportunities, and ensure ec<strong>on</strong>omicaccountability and transparency. Equally,the absence of such rights undermines ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment and hinders governance. Analysis ofthe World Bank’s Country Per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance and Instituti<strong>on</strong>alAssessment (CPIA) ratings <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2005 indicatesthat <strong>on</strong> a scale of 1 to 6 (with 1 being thelowest score), <strong>on</strong>ly five of 76 developing countriesscored 4 <strong>on</strong> objective measurement of propertyrights and rule-based governance. 6 As all five aresmall island states, this indicati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>firms thatproperty rights of the absolute majority of the peoplein developing countries are not protected intheory or practice, c<strong>on</strong>tracts are not en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced, andregistries and other instituti<strong>on</strong>s required to protectproperty functi<strong>on</strong> poorly or not at all. 7Especially Vulnerable GroupsCertain groups are frequently and systematicallydisenfranchised through lack of access to propertyrights in many countries. Women, who c<strong>on</strong>stitutehalf of the world’s populati<strong>on</strong>, own around10 percent of the world’s property. 8 Virginia Woolfeloquently expressed the l<strong>on</strong>g arch of history thathas not <strong>on</strong>ly excluded women from property in64


the West, but that has made entire state instituti<strong>on</strong>smasculine preserves. 9 Even when womenhave de jure property rights, their de facto c<strong>on</strong>trolof land is tenuous, and men largely mediatedaccess. In Imo and Abia states in Nigeria, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, average household farms are 9.8 hectares,of which <strong>on</strong>ly 2.4 hectares are allocatedto women. However, this land is not a claim, butrather a lease, which women must organise fromtheir husbands. Further, widows cannot own land;their husband’s family keep it in trust <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theirchildren. 10 As Robin Nielsen has pointed out:‘At various stages in women’s lives, their rightsto land are dependent <strong>on</strong> fathers, brothers, husbandsand s<strong>on</strong>s. A more precarious foundati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>land rights is difficult to imagine.’ 11 Ensuring thatwomen’s names appear <strong>on</strong> land records, that theirrights are enshrined in communal property systems,and that inheritance rights of widows anddaughters are established and protected, wouldgo a l<strong>on</strong>g way towards improving their c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>.This is essential to empowerment and the promoti<strong>on</strong>of entrepreneurial activity and should beplaced at the centre of property re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts.Equally, indigenous people around the world tendto suffer from weak or prescribed property rightsnot adequately recognised by law. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se groupsoften hold land collectively, so ownership andaccess patterns do not always fit easily into imported,n<strong>on</strong>-indigenous property systems of absoluteand individual nature. As they are largelydisenfranchised, the customary land rights of theindigenous tend to be overlooked. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> AbayandaPygmies in Uganda, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, have beenentirely dispossessed of their land; they haveendured persistent lack of recogniti<strong>on</strong> by thecentral government of legitimate claims to theirproperty. Indeed, the problem is far from solvedin developed countries. In 1902, Norway passedlegislati<strong>on</strong> requiring full knowledge of the Norwegianlanguage <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property ownership, effectivelymaking it impossible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the indigenous Sami toown land.In 2004 an Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Organisati<strong>on</strong>(ILO) expert committee c<strong>on</strong>cluded that an Actpassed in 2003 to rectify centuries of exclusi<strong>on</strong>arypractices still did not meet the minimumstandards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ILO c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the rights ofindigenous and tribal peoples. 12 Global re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mof property rights regimes must allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malrecogniti<strong>on</strong> of customary land rights as the basis<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> inclusive property systems that include indigenouspeoples. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are some good examplesin <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Native Title Act of 1993in Australia, and the landmark Te Ture WhenuaMaori Act in New Zealand, both of which respectthe customary land rights of indigenous groups.Although time will tell if laws of this nature canchange deeply entrenched exclusi<strong>on</strong>ary practices,but legal empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor indigenousgroups will certainly remain key to tackling thischallenge in both OECD and developing countries.Urban slum dwellers are also excluded from<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal property systems. At least a third of theworld’s poor, or a billi<strong>on</strong> people, are living inslums without legal protecti<strong>on</strong> of their assets. 13Ir<strong>on</strong>ically, it is often insecurity of land tenureand wr<strong>on</strong>gful loss of land in rural areas that encouragethe poor to escape, while their propertyrights in urban areas are no less tenuous. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reality of urban slum dwellers is sub-standardhousing c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceful evicti<strong>on</strong>s, extorti<strong>on</strong>,social exclusi<strong>on</strong>, and envir<strong>on</strong>mental degradati<strong>on</strong>,am<strong>on</strong>g other problems. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> situati<strong>on</strong> preventsdevelopment of adequate housing stock and theemergence of robust property and credit markets.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal property systems are often perpetuatedin c<strong>on</strong>flict-affected countries by flows of refugeesand Internally Displaced Pers<strong>on</strong>s (IDPs) from ru-65


al to urban areas, and this leads to further insecurityand overcrowding.<strong>Legal</strong> access to property rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> various groupsis clearly an over-arching and universal issuethat should be at the centre of global ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts toempower the poor; but it has in fact received verylittle coherent analysis to date. To unpack therelati<strong>on</strong>ship between poverty and property rightswe must understand that it is these rights thatprovide the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> globalec<strong>on</strong>omy grew very slowly until the beginning ofthe 19 th Century. Be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e then, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thousandsof years, notes Jeffrey Sachs, ‘there had beenvirtually no sustained ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth in theworld’. 14 However, with the advent of the industrialrevoluti<strong>on</strong> and ec<strong>on</strong>omic expansi<strong>on</strong>, assetsexpanded and property rights evolved. Slowly theidea of private property ownership came to underpinec<strong>on</strong>omic development in the West. Whilesocial, ec<strong>on</strong>omic and political stability was upsetby two World Wars and the Great Depressi<strong>on</strong>, theGI Bill of Rights in the United States, the MarshallPlan and the incipient ec<strong>on</strong>omic and politicaluni<strong>on</strong> in Europe, and rapid development inEast Asia supported the growth of a middle-classthat led to further c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> of legal propertysystems in these regi<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> frompredominantly extralegal property systems to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malproperty rights entrenched in law has sincecome to support functi<strong>on</strong>ing market ec<strong>on</strong>omiesand polities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Building Blocks of the PropertySystemThis transiti<strong>on</strong> has reduced global poverty substantially,but as outlined above, billi<strong>on</strong>s of peoplearound the world still lack secure propertyrights, which hinders their ec<strong>on</strong>omic, politicaland social security. In order to examine how povertycan best be relieved, and why access to propertyrights is fundamental to the empowermentof the poor, it is necessary to identify buildingblocks of a fully-functi<strong>on</strong>al property system. Sucha system operates in the following four ways:1) As a system of rules that defines the bundleof rights and obligati<strong>on</strong>s between people andassets. 15 Property ownership creates ties thatbind individual citizens together through the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> of networks of ec<strong>on</strong>omic and legalrights and corresp<strong>on</strong>ding obligati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>credible en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of these rights and obligati<strong>on</strong>srequires a judicial mechanism thatallows <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> equitable, transparent and efficientdispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>.2) As a system of governance. Property systemsare a central facet of state functi<strong>on</strong>ality, andas such are an important measurement of fiduciaryand administrative effectiveness. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>instituti<strong>on</strong>al order of the state is based <strong>on</strong>technical rules and relati<strong>on</strong>ships which defineinteracti<strong>on</strong>s between stakeholders, rangingfrom direct ownership of land to promulgati<strong>on</strong>of rules that govern security of land andhouse tenure, land planning, z<strong>on</strong>ing, taxingand other aspects of property management.Technological innovati<strong>on</strong>, which has radicallyreduced the cost of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, has generatedthe possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> further transparency and accountabilityin property systems as an instrumentof governance.3) As a functi<strong>on</strong>ing market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the exchange ofassets. A fully functi<strong>on</strong>al property system allowsland, houses, moveable property, equityshares, and ideas to be trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med into assetsto be bought and sold at rates determinedby market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces. This subjects the exchangeof property to a level of transparency and accountability,and allows <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the developmentof financial mechanisms — including credit66


and insurance — to facilitate transacti<strong>on</strong>s andimprove ec<strong>on</strong>omic outcomes. Land, housesand moveable property can thus be leveraged,and assets trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med from static investmentsinto capital which can be bought andsold. However, property rights are a necessarybut not sufficient prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the developmentof these financial mechanisms; theyalso develop through partnership between themarket, special funds targeted at access tofinance, and the state.4) As an instrument of social policy. In the absenceor failure of the market, the state oftenplays a direct role in addressing the needs ofthe poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> state has at its disposal instrumentsthat can be used to endow its citizenswith assets as they relate to property, suchas public housing, low interest loans and thedistributi<strong>on</strong> of state land. Such instrumentshelp to overcome natural competiti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> assets.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> state also supports social cohesi<strong>on</strong>through the development of co-ownership ofinfrastructure and services by government andthe citizen, supporting the equilibrium betweenindividual and collective interests. Provisi<strong>on</strong>of infrastructure by the state criticallyaffects the value and desirability of assets,and can there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e fundamentally affect opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor.Dysfuncti<strong>on</strong>alities in PropertyManagement<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se four key building blocks can be viewed as acoherent framework through which to understandproperty rights. It follows that analysis of theseblocks allows us to identify where dysfuncti<strong>on</strong>alitiesin property management might arise andwhere there are disc<strong>on</strong>nects within key elementsof this framework. As far as the poor are c<strong>on</strong>cerned,they have trouble getting property in thefirst place (unfairly limited access). Where theyhave assets, their rights are often not adequatelyrecognised, or en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced, or given full backing ofthe law, and are c<strong>on</strong>sequently vulnerable to beinglost. Unfairly limited access to property and insecurityof assets are caused by dysfuncti<strong>on</strong>alitiesin the property system that can be understoodfourfold:1) Misalignment of social practice and legalprovisi<strong>on</strong>. Social practice and law rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceeach other when aligned towards comm<strong>on</strong>objectives, but when misaligned can underminestate legitimacy and accountability andweaken ties of citizenship. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> must evolveorganically to suit the c<strong>on</strong>text in which it is tobe applied and should not be perceived as theinstrument through which a minority imposesits power. <strong>Legal</strong> aspects of property systemsmust grow from land practices <strong>on</strong> the groundand incorporate customary interacti<strong>on</strong>s andnetworks. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re have been two comm<strong>on</strong> sourcesof misalignment. Firstly, some states, particularlyduring the col<strong>on</strong>ial period, imposedproperty systems <strong>on</strong> vast tracts of land thatwere previously regulated through customaryregimes of rights and obligati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> resultwas a major gap between daily practices of thepeople and requirements of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal law. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly,in urban areas, as de Soto has pointedout, ill-c<strong>on</strong>ceived laws have <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced milli<strong>on</strong>s ofpeople into in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, as gaining access toland <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> housing is a lengthy process, measuredin terms of years if not decades. 162) Misuse of rules governing property. While rules<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property systems may be both appropriateand equitable, they may still be open toabuse by those in power. Rules are resourcesthat can be subverted to serve the interests ofthe few, through corrupti<strong>on</strong> and lack of transparency,rather than acting as a framework67


<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment of the many. Equally, landregulati<strong>on</strong>s, rather than providing a frameworkwithin which parameters <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property managementare set and transacti<strong>on</strong>s enabled, canbecome mechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> restricti<strong>on</strong> of propertyrights and bureaucratic mismanagement.3) Lack of access to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and justice.Even where cadastres, land registers and otherrepositories of property titles, records anddocuments exist, restricti<strong>on</strong> of access to suchin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> reduces the transparency and efficiencyof property transacti<strong>on</strong>s. Governmentsmust work to make in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> propertyavailable to the general public and seek tocollect further data and opini<strong>on</strong> in innovativeways through the promoti<strong>on</strong> of opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public debate <strong>on</strong> property and citizen resourcerights, and strengthening of knowledgesharing and analysis <strong>on</strong> these issues.4) Misuse of eminent domain. Corrupt governmentscan use the inherent power of the stateto seize private property and thus c<strong>on</strong>fiscateassets of the poor in the name of the publicgood. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> primary remedy against wr<strong>on</strong>gfulor unjust loss of property is a just policy ofland acquisiti<strong>on</strong> and resettlement; it can includeinnovative approaches, such as offeringpartnerships to the poor in developing assetscreated from investment in infrastructure andservices. Internati<strong>on</strong>al financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s,particularly the World Bank and the AsianDevelopment Bank, moved systematically inthis way in the 1990s to address the adverseimpacts that developmental projects had <strong>on</strong>the standard of living of the poor. At the nati<strong>on</strong>allevel, however, practices differ widelyand abuse, with regard to use of eminent domain(<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> depriving the poor of their assets),c<strong>on</strong>tinues to be a problem. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of compulsoryacquisiti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms is necessary,as dem<strong>on</strong>strated most palpably in Zimbabwerecently, <strong>on</strong>e of the few countries today whichc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>ally permits appropriati<strong>on</strong> withoutpayment of any compensati<strong>on</strong>. 17 Review of 20land acquisiti<strong>on</strong> laws in Sub-Saharan Africa 18indicates three sources of this type of legaldisempowerment: (1) process of acquisiti<strong>on</strong>,wherein, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, compensati<strong>on</strong> valuingbilli<strong>on</strong>s of dollars remains unpaid in someregi<strong>on</strong>s without clear avenues of redress; (2)the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> compensati<strong>on</strong> payment, whichroutinely fails to take into account real coststo the loss of land, and (3) manipulati<strong>on</strong>,through purposeful or poorly specified definiti<strong>on</strong>,of what c<strong>on</strong>stitutes ‘public purpose’. 19Property Rights and <strong>Legal</strong>EmpowermentProperty rights are defined through law, andthere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the poor, ascitizens, can <strong>on</strong>ly come about through the protecti<strong>on</strong>of those rights. However, legal status canhave strikingly different impacts up<strong>on</strong> citizenship:it can become an instrument <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the creati<strong>on</strong> ofopportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> exercising rights, create entitlementsto rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> specific categories of people,or repress or deny c<strong>on</strong>testati<strong>on</strong> of those rights toothers. H.L.A. Hart’s distincti<strong>on</strong> between internaland external views of the law shown in Table 1 isinstructive. 20Since internal actors are positi<strong>on</strong>ed in a hierarchy,the extent to which legal status producesloyalty to the social order depends <strong>on</strong> feedbackloops. ‘Loops’ between and am<strong>on</strong>g the actors affectthe degree of efficiency and effectiveness ofthe administrators in delivering rights or en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cingobligati<strong>on</strong>s in a manner that incorporates accountability.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘user’ perspective is essential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thelegitimacy of the system, as legitimacy is the outcomeof the degree to which people, <strong>on</strong>ce granted68


Table 1 Mapping the dynamics of legal statusExternal<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> public, social movements<strong>Legal</strong> community of practiceJudicial Review, civil society and mediaExcluded/ineligible peopleInternal<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authorizing envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rule-making (Parliament, C<strong>on</strong>gress,Cabinet Board of Corporati<strong>on</strong>s)Composers/Drafters (C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s, primary, sec<strong>on</strong>darylegislati<strong>on</strong>, by-laws, manuals)Administrators/OrganisersUsers/citizensa particular legal status or set of rights, such asproperty rights, come to identify and endorse thesocial order so produced. External actors are positi<strong>on</strong>edto push the fr<strong>on</strong>tiers of the existing socialorder by questi<strong>on</strong>ing the balance between solidarityand inequality. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y catalyse changes to existingcitizenship arrangements, in questi<strong>on</strong>ing thefairness or effectiveness of an existing legal status,and in the creati<strong>on</strong> of new legal status <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> specificgroups. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> creati<strong>on</strong> and expansi<strong>on</strong> of citizenshiprights is a process of c<strong>on</strong>testati<strong>on</strong> that can lead t<strong>on</strong>ew interpretati<strong>on</strong>s of old laws and the promulgati<strong>on</strong>of new laws, or the creati<strong>on</strong> of new mechanismsto deal with issues that do not fit into anexisting framework. Thus, groups that questi<strong>on</strong> thestatus quo can prove that the law is malleable, justas indigenous groups have fought <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and w<strong>on</strong>,recogniti<strong>on</strong> of customary land rights in Australia orNew Zealand.However, the provisi<strong>on</strong> of property rights inlaw does not always guarantee equality inpractice. While states can attempt to balanceinequality and solidarity, discriminati<strong>on</strong> and socialclassificati<strong>on</strong>s remain entrenched in manysocieties. Inequality can stem from deep-rootedcultural distincti<strong>on</strong>s such as caste, gender andrace, and the challenge then is to create c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property rights not just at the legal level,but through mechanisms that can fundamentallychange mental models and social practices at alllevels of society. Even in the European Uni<strong>on</strong>,where equality of men and women is a fundamentalaxiom of policy, gender mainstreaming insocial policy still remains a significant challenge,according to a recent European <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> report<strong>on</strong> social inclusi<strong>on</strong>. 21<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> degree to which an order is open or closed, toextending legal status to new groups or to changingthe status of existing groups, is an importanttest of its capacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> coping with change. Evenwhen creati<strong>on</strong> of status is open in theory, mechanismsare needed to create trust in the socialorder. If property rights are legally extended toa previously disenfranchised group, that groupmust believe that their property will not be seizedthrough misuse of eminent domain.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, c<strong>on</strong>text-based legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is critical togovernance in developing countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re can beno blanket approach: expansi<strong>on</strong> of property rightsin a coherent manner requires understanding oftrends and a tailoring of provisi<strong>on</strong>s to c<strong>on</strong>text.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re must be a degree of coherence to lawsbased <strong>on</strong> fundamental rules, or those laws willnot be respected. If de jure property rights do notcorresp<strong>on</strong>d with de facto property practices andcustoms, the subsequent legal misalignment willundermine rather than strengthen the system.Disorder and dysfuncti<strong>on</strong> has its own stakeholders,and if resources are seen as zero-sum,change can be perceived as highly threatening byentrenched interests.69


Property systems c<strong>on</strong>sist of a bundle of rights andobligati<strong>on</strong>s. In OECD countries, an entire seriesof legal innovati<strong>on</strong>s has evolved to allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> cooperativearrangements that underpin this dynamicand support transparent, effective property-basedec<strong>on</strong>omies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> same type of thinking has notbeen applied to developing-country c<strong>on</strong>texts toexamine precisely how property arrangementscould be modified, and interacti<strong>on</strong>s codified, inways that would allow the poor to leverage theirassets and become legitimate stakeholders inglobal property systems. Urban slums representland that could be a valuable asset when c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizedin a different way as part of coherenturban planning strategies. Latent assets mustbe leveraged and their stakeholders — the poor— brought into dynamic new partnerships toalign law and practice in ways that allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thesystemic expansi<strong>on</strong> of property rights.Key Elements of a Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m StrategyThis process creates both a nati<strong>on</strong>al and globalpublic good, and to bring it about governmentsof developing countries must enter into adouble compact - with their citizens and the internati<strong>on</strong>alcommunity. To level the playing field <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor and operate in a manner that best servesthe interests of the disenfranchised, internati<strong>on</strong>alactors must develop l<strong>on</strong>g-term partnerships withnati<strong>on</strong>al governments <strong>on</strong> property rights as partof the broader ec<strong>on</strong>omic governance agenda. Are<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> effectively functi<strong>on</strong>ing propertysystems that empower the poor should be based<strong>on</strong> land tenure security, creati<strong>on</strong> of opportunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>investment, and adequate management of risk.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> elements of such a strategy must:1) Promote Legitimacy by Adequate Participati<strong>on</strong>and Deliberati<strong>on</strong>. In general, future re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m willrequire a legitimate state. For implementati<strong>on</strong>at all levels, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms must be based <strong>on</strong>deliberati<strong>on</strong> and inputs from those that theyare intended to affect. This will bring focus <strong>on</strong>relevant issues, engender acceptance by localcommunities, and reduce the cost of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.In Peru between 1996 and 2000, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example,3,500 meetings were held <strong>on</strong> land titling processesin different settlements around the country,helping to improve community satisfacti<strong>on</strong>with property re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts. 22 In particular, thegroups outlined above - women, indigenousgroups, and urban slum dwellers - and otherexcluded groups, must be given special attenti<strong>on</strong>as part of this process. Support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiativessuch as the establishment of coaliti<strong>on</strong>sbetween urban and rural poor around comm<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>cerns including the effects of the rural exodus<strong>on</strong> rural ec<strong>on</strong>omies and urban poverty are aproductive starting point. 232) Support Parallel Interventi<strong>on</strong>s. Implementati<strong>on</strong>of rules that underpin a functi<strong>on</strong>ing system <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>access to, and registrati<strong>on</strong> of, property, do notautomatically create the mechanisms necessaryto support this system. By giving attenti<strong>on</strong> tothe four building blocks of the property system,governments must carefully plan and sequencethe interventi<strong>on</strong>s that will create the corollaryfinancial and legal instruments that underpineffective property rights and facilitate accessto managerial ability, technology, credit, andmarkets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> new property owners to becomecompetitive. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> evoluti<strong>on</strong> of efficient financialmarkets will depend <strong>on</strong> the ability to use land,and other property, as collateral. In developedcountries, more than two thirds of small businessloans are secured against land and realestate. Experience in South Africa and Brazildem<strong>on</strong>strates that unc<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al avenues(e.g. partnerships and joint ventures with oldland owners) may be a useful first step. Governmentsshould also develop methods <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in-70


creasing finance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and post-landacquisiti<strong>on</strong> services, including land banks,land-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>-debt schemes and land <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxes. 243) Facilitate Private Sector Involvement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>state needs to set the parameters within whichprivate sector investment can take place, andremove any disincentives to this process. Fees<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property transacti<strong>on</strong>s, which in some developingcountries can be as high as 30 percent,act as an unnecessary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of taxati<strong>on</strong> thatinhibits the free exchange of land throughmarket mechanisms and excludes the poor.Official land taxes must also be set at an af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dablelevel <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor and subsidies andtax provisi<strong>on</strong>s that provide distorting privilegesto large-scale farmers should be removed. InMexico, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, certain groups ‘prefer notto regularise the land <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> human settlementto evade having to paying land tax, which promotesin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality in land markets.’ 25 Investmentclimate surveys indicate that access toland was the main obstacle to c<strong>on</strong>ducting andexpanding business by 57 percent of the enterprisesinterviewed in Ethiopia, 35 percentin Bangladesh and 25 percent in Tanzania andKenya.4) Promote Property Rights through Individualand Corporate Ownership. Property law shouldoffer clear and simple opti<strong>on</strong>s of legal pers<strong>on</strong>alityand corporate ownership <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> smallbusinesses and corporative associati<strong>on</strong>s of thepoor. <strong>Legal</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>ality so designed opens upa wide range of possibilities of ownership byhuman individuals, by members of collectives,and by collectives. Pro-poor property rights systemsfacilitate the ability of people to pool andleverage modest resources and limit liabilitiesin case of business failure or exit of partners.One of the keys to ec<strong>on</strong>omic success of smallentrepreneurs in the developing world is thelimited liability of business owners, thus offeringthe possibility of c<strong>on</strong>trolled failure withoutdisastrous ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>sequences <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thevulnerable individuals involved. This legal instrumentof limited corporate liability has to beextended to the poor micro-entrepreneurs andrural producers. It c<strong>on</strong>stitutes <strong>on</strong>e of the mainadvantages of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality of corporate ownershipand can trump unavoidable disadvantages.5) Create Systems <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Collateralising Moveableand Intangible Property. Although many of thecitizens of the developing world lack securerights to use and transfer real property, mostof them own some tangible (moveable) or intangibleproperty. 26 To the extent that this typeof property is held securely and can be used toaccess credit and to create and grow businesses,the poor will have increased opportunities.Experience in a variety of developing countries(Georgia, Madagascar, Colombia, Albania, Bosniaam<strong>on</strong>g them) suggests that there are importantlegal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that would allow the poorto leverage movable and intangible property.6) Co-management of Natural Resources. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> majorityof the rural poor depend to a large extent<strong>on</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-arable resources such as <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests, pastures,swamplands, and fishing grounds. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seresources require careful management to avoidrent-seeking and corrupt practices that resultin envir<strong>on</strong>mental degradati<strong>on</strong> and ec<strong>on</strong>omicinefficiencies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> state should enhance theasset base of the poor by enabling communitybasedownership and management of privatecomm<strong>on</strong>s, but it will have to play the role ofc<strong>on</strong>flict manager am<strong>on</strong>g the communities andam<strong>on</strong>g individuals. In the case of fossil energyresources requiring capital intensive extracti<strong>on</strong>,treatment and distributi<strong>on</strong>, the state shouldutilise transparent and fair aucti<strong>on</strong> procedureswhen involving the private sector, linked to71


c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality of local community development.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se procedures could be regulatedand implemented <strong>on</strong> the basis of multilateralcharters. 27 In the case of state co-ownershipof fossil energy reserves, the local populati<strong>on</strong>sshould be included in the chain of value additi<strong>on</strong>by tradable shares in general public funds.Distributing am<strong>on</strong>g the poor shares or other<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of ownership participati<strong>on</strong> in state ownedcompanies that exploit the natural resourceswill provide them with capital that, inter alia,can propel the expansi<strong>on</strong> of small businesses.Another opti<strong>on</strong> is distributing titles to specialfunds created by governments to invest profitsyielded by commodities. 287) Utilise Modern Technology. Manual systemsof land registrati<strong>on</strong> are highly labour intensiveand lead to significant error and duplicati<strong>on</strong>.Moreover, the costs of manual land survey andregistrati<strong>on</strong> processes are often prohibitive.Recent advances in technology, including thewidespread availability of satellite imageryand handheld GPS devices, together with instituti<strong>on</strong>alarrangements that put local actorsin charge of systematic adjudicati<strong>on</strong>, can significantlyreduce the cost and ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t of issuingland registrati<strong>on</strong> documents. Moreover, moderntechnology can help to improve transparencyand at the same time make land administrati<strong>on</strong>more accessible. 29 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are caveatsto this process, identified in the report.Based <strong>on</strong> these principles, developing countrygovernments, supported by the internati<strong>on</strong>alcommunity, must devise a series of innovative,pro-poor land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m policies that are distinctlyfocused <strong>on</strong> ensuring that more of the benefits ofproperty systems accrue to those at the very bottomof the ec<strong>on</strong>omic ladder. A careful stocktakingof such ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts already underway in various partsof the world, including analysis of c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s thatgave rise to such ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts, and possibilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theirexpansi<strong>on</strong>, will be instructive. We can developtransiti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m mechanisms from experiencein the Philippines, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, where the nati<strong>on</strong>algovernment employs intermediate instruments ofland tenure, such as land proclamati<strong>on</strong>s, to assurethe poor that they will not be evicted fromland they occupy, and that social services will beimproved while plot ownership is <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malised. 30Or we c<strong>on</strong>sider how the South African experiencewith Mzansi accounts, providing low-fee banking<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector,could be replicated elsewhere. 31 Modalities exist toempower the poor through property rights, but wemust now scale up and catalyse them.C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong><strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor through propertyrights requires sustained ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts. Property systemsthat exclude large segments of the global populati<strong>on</strong>from property rights have to be disc<strong>on</strong>tinuedand we must expand the z<strong>on</strong>e of legitimate landtenure through improved access and security.Developing country governments must enter intoa compact with their own citizens and with theinternati<strong>on</strong>al community to support this re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> aid community understands that propertyrights must be a central tenet of any ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts toreduce poverty, and allocates funding <strong>on</strong> thisbasis. Today, the key challenge is to c<strong>on</strong>solidatethinking and draw good practice from effectiveinterventi<strong>on</strong>s to date to improve pro-poor outcomes,develop effective land management instituti<strong>on</strong>s,establish clear rules <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the managementof public land, and strengthen the instituti<strong>on</strong>alframework and mechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> land transfer andaccess. Property rights are too central to humandignity and prosperity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> current thinking andpractice to c<strong>on</strong>tinue. Only with empowermentthrough property rights can we truly seek to reduceglobal poverty and reduce inequality.72


I. Introducti<strong>on</strong>As these lines are being written, close to30,000 of India’s roughly 170 milli<strong>on</strong> landlesspeople are marching peacefully to Delhi<strong>on</strong> the highway. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y demand not to be drivenoff their land just because it was declared stateproperty; they demand property documents or the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal registrati<strong>on</strong> of documents in their possessi<strong>on</strong>;they demanded that unused state land beallocated to them, and they demand state protecti<strong>on</strong>against violent guerrilla movements. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>fulfilment of these demands, and the soluti<strong>on</strong> tomany other property-related problems identifiedin this report, requires str<strong>on</strong>g, sustained and c<strong>on</strong>text-basedre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. Such re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m has to be foundedin political will and the associati<strong>on</strong>al power of thepoor, exemplified by the marchers in India.<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor is a frameworkof acti<strong>on</strong> which takes such demands seriously.It recommends the promoti<strong>on</strong> of domestic legaland administrative frameworks providing the pooropportunities to use their talents and to trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mtheir impressive ec<strong>on</strong>omic ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts into anincreased and secured asset base. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> agendaimplies a general re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of the law from an instrumentof dominati<strong>on</strong> into a system of effectiveprotecti<strong>on</strong>s and opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. 32On the input side, the emphasis of legal empowermentis placed <strong>on</strong> participatory and accountable<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of law-making and public administrati<strong>on</strong>,giving voice to the poor and increasedownership of the framing of their legal and socialenvir<strong>on</strong>ment. Regarding the means, legal empowermentstresses the critical importance ofthe following: granting legal identity and accessto justice to all human pers<strong>on</strong>s, small businesscorporati<strong>on</strong>s, and civil society associati<strong>on</strong>s (seeChapter 1 of this report); securing property rightsof the poor as asset holders through comprehensiveand c<strong>on</strong>text-based property rights systems;protecting the poor as workers (see Chapter 3),and creating an enabling business envir<strong>on</strong>ment<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> small entrepreneurs and the self-employed(Chapter 4). On the output side, a result-orientedlegal empowerment agenda stresses effectiveprotecti<strong>on</strong> of livelihoods of the poor and, moreoriginally, measurable creati<strong>on</strong> of new opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> diversifying livelihoods, thereby improvinglives. Escape from the poverty trap and creating amore decent life are seen as the principal aims.Property rights stand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the bundle of libertiesand claim rights tied to the allocati<strong>on</strong> of aresource to a natural or legal pers<strong>on</strong>, corporati<strong>on</strong>,collectivity, associati<strong>on</strong>, etc. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>cept of propertyrights as human rights and as part of <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor implies two agendas:legally en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced protecti<strong>on</strong> of the assets of thepoor, and general promoti<strong>on</strong> of access to propertyby the poor.Through sustainable ownership and/or securityof tenure 33 individuals and communities becomemore aut<strong>on</strong>omous. Even with modest assets, asholders of property rights, individuals and groupsbecome more active as independent members oftheir communities and nati<strong>on</strong>s. Private propertyrights allow people to pool their assets into transparentstructures of co-ownership with fair exitopti<strong>on</strong>s. This is critical <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor who have veryfew assets but who can achieve social and ec<strong>on</strong>omicleverage by pooling assets into legally recognisedcomm<strong>on</strong> or community property. Reliableand equitable property rights systems help settlecompeting property claims and facilitate theidentificati<strong>on</strong> of resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities and liabilities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> increased social stability and trust emanatingfrom robust property rights systems create appropriateenvir<strong>on</strong>ments <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business and investment.Secure rights to use and trade property providestr<strong>on</strong>g incentives to maintain and c<strong>on</strong>serve re-73


sources. Individuals and groups with such rightstend to invest in the resources they hold. In general,property rights give people a horiz<strong>on</strong> to planthe future <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themselves and their communities.Structure and Goal of this ChapterN<strong>on</strong>e of the above-menti<strong>on</strong>ed benefits can beachieved easily with <strong>on</strong>e-size-fits-all models. Thischapter elaborates the main features of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mwith a special but n<strong>on</strong>-exclusive emphasis <strong>on</strong>the poor. Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 identifies the most vulnerablesegments of society and the relati<strong>on</strong> of theirpoverty and exclusi<strong>on</strong> to the problem of propertyrights protecti<strong>on</strong>. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 briefly assesses thebarriers and facilitators of change, drawing attenti<strong>on</strong>to social actors as well as structural c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sfavouring status quo or change, while Secti<strong>on</strong>4 c<strong>on</strong>tains a c<strong>on</strong>cise compilati<strong>on</strong> of less<strong>on</strong>sand experienced c<strong>on</strong>sequences of past re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mactivities, and prepares the ground <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the maindiscussi<strong>on</strong>, in Secti<strong>on</strong> 5, <strong>on</strong> proposals within thefour building blocks of the property system. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>proposals aim at re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the property system(viewed as an arrangement of rules defining orenabling bundles and bearers of property rights)in such a manner that it would enable the poor— especially women and indigenous communities— to access and to secure property. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> suggesti<strong>on</strong>sshould also help to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the propertysystem so it could serve as a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of governance,as a functi<strong>on</strong>ing market of assets (including thepoor in the chains of value additi<strong>on</strong>), and as asystem of social policy with targeted measuresof capacity building and access to property andhousing.Parallel re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m work, sustained by c<strong>on</strong>stantm<strong>on</strong>itoring in all four dimensi<strong>on</strong>s, is advocatedin order to achieve real progress. Comm<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal features of policy design and prioritisingare dealt with in a special paragraph of Secti<strong>on</strong>5. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> establishment of fully functi<strong>on</strong>al propertysystems and positive effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor is firstand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emost a nati<strong>on</strong>al and local re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m issuedemanding the renegotiati<strong>on</strong> of instituti<strong>on</strong>al, legal,and social relati<strong>on</strong>s at the nati<strong>on</strong>al and locallevel. However, an additi<strong>on</strong>al secti<strong>on</strong> of this reportalso points to important subsidiary and stabilisingacti<strong>on</strong> by d<strong>on</strong>or countries and multilateralarrangements.This chapter deals with the most general featuresof pro-poor property re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and is thus not to beread as a nati<strong>on</strong>al or local implementati<strong>on</strong> report.It builds, however, <strong>on</strong> less<strong>on</strong>s and practices thathave proven beneficial in many different c<strong>on</strong>textsand that have been highlighted in numerous nati<strong>on</strong>aland grass roots c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s of the CLEP.Our recommendati<strong>on</strong>s, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, deserve to beseriously c<strong>on</strong>sidered and further tailored to local-realityc<strong>on</strong>text by property rights re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in thedeveloping world.Although not repeatedly menti<strong>on</strong>ed throughoutthis chapter, the members of our working groupacknowledge the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts of numerous governments,internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s, and NGOs inthe field of property rights. And as many membersare themselves part of past and <strong>on</strong>going ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tsin the field, our chapter was not written withany pretensi<strong>on</strong> to invent a ‘wheel’. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> intent isthat it would serve to raise political awarenessand communicate a set of selected policy opti<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decisi<strong>on</strong> makers in the hope of improving substantiallyequitable property rights protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor and societies at large. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> general treatmentof such a sensitive and c<strong>on</strong>text-dependentissue implies an inevitable trade-off between simplicityand comprehensiveness.It should be noted at the outset that the chair,rapporteur and c<strong>on</strong>tributors to this chapter(named at the beginning of this volume) have all74


c<strong>on</strong>tributed to its substance. But as drafted andsynthesised by the rapporteur, the c<strong>on</strong>tent mightnot always represent all the viewpoints and priorities.Positi<strong>on</strong>s taken should thus not be directlyattributed to all c<strong>on</strong>tributors — some positi<strong>on</strong>s,in fact, remain c<strong>on</strong>troversial am<strong>on</strong>g them. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reare two general points in relati<strong>on</strong> to which thec<strong>on</strong>tributors voiced c<strong>on</strong>flicting views to the rapporteur:the first c<strong>on</strong>cerns the role of the state;the sec<strong>on</strong>d, the role of the market. While somesee the state as an indispensable part of the soluti<strong>on</strong>to the problem of faltering property rights<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor, others emphasise that it is ratherpart of the problem or even the root cause. And,while some see the market as an opportunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor to work themselves out of poverty, othersstress the fact that market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces marginalize thepoor and drive them into misery.Acloser look reveals that these diagnosticview points are often c<strong>on</strong>text-dependent. Torealise property rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor, both the stateas enabler and lender of last resort in regulati<strong>on</strong>and rule implementati<strong>on</strong>, as well as the marketas prime producer of resources, need close attenti<strong>on</strong>.Both state and market have indeed beenneglecting or harming the poor, but in the fightagainst poverty there is no alternative to thedynamic relati<strong>on</strong> between a re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med and morelegitimate state and a functi<strong>on</strong>al market that includesthe poor in the value chains. This chapterthere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e stresses the dynamic interdependenceof state and market and the equal importanceof their re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to empower thepoor through property rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is c<strong>on</strong>sensusam<strong>on</strong>g the members of the working group whichprepared this chapter that the state as suchshould not be the default owner of land propertyand natural resources. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> state is, however, indispensableas regulator, enabler, and aucti<strong>on</strong>eerof equitable property relati<strong>on</strong>s. Increasing thelegitimacy of the state thus bel<strong>on</strong>gs at the centreof the nati<strong>on</strong>al and multilateral agenda of propertyrights protecti<strong>on</strong>.Realisati<strong>on</strong> of property rights is about creating apositive feedback loop between the functi<strong>on</strong>alityof property governance by the state <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>eside, and the meaning this systemic functi<strong>on</strong>alityhas <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the people in their everyday life and customs.Importantly, neither of these two elementsis to be understood as rigid and unchangeable. 34Culture and customs are subject to c<strong>on</strong>stantchange due to urbanisati<strong>on</strong>, populati<strong>on</strong> growth,migrati<strong>on</strong>, social differentiati<strong>on</strong>, technologicaldevelopment, etc., and so are the state’s instituti<strong>on</strong>alrules and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal procedures. If propertyrights are to bring substantial benefits to the globalpoor, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malised property systems of poorcountries and the social practices have to evolvetogether and in resp<strong>on</strong>se to each other.75


2. Faltering Property Rights:the Nature and Scale of theProblemAbsence, unjust allocati<strong>on</strong>, or insecurity of propertyrights harm the poor and hinder sustainabledevelopment of a society. 35 Faltering propertyrights protecti<strong>on</strong> is related to the disenfranchisementof billi<strong>on</strong>s of poor people. In many cases,the inappropriate property rights system is theimmediate cause of c<strong>on</strong>tinued social, ec<strong>on</strong>omic,and political disenfranchisement. This secti<strong>on</strong>will highlight the most critical areas as well asthe most vulnerable groups of people affected bythe dire c<strong>on</strong>sequences of the absence or dysfuncti<strong>on</strong>of property rights protecti<strong>on</strong>.Growing Slums and <strong>Legal</strong> VoidsAt least a third of the world’s poor live in irregularsettlements without coherent legal protecti<strong>on</strong>of their assets. Populati<strong>on</strong> and urban settlementgrowth projecti<strong>on</strong>s predict an aggravati<strong>on</strong> of theproblem. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> UN Human Settlements Programmeholds that over the next 25 years more than 2billi<strong>on</strong> urban dwellers could be added to the closeto 1 billi<strong>on</strong> now living in slums, with some 2.825billi<strong>on</strong> requiring housing and urban services by2030. If no acti<strong>on</strong> is taken most of this growthwill occur outside the legally protected sector. 37<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sequences of the exclusi<strong>on</strong> of the poor asa result of rapid urbanisati<strong>on</strong> and modernisati<strong>on</strong>are being acutely manifested around the world. Inthe final analysis, am<strong>on</strong>g all the causal factors <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>displacement, first and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emost is lack of securityof tenure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor, who have no en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceableproperty rights or access to justice.Box 1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> world’s poor:a demographic noteGlobally 53 percent of the populati<strong>on</strong> is defined aspoor by the ‘living under US$2 a day standard’ or3.4 billi<strong>on</strong> people. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor live in mainly six regi<strong>on</strong>sand particularly three: South Central Asia (whichincludes populous India), the even more populousChina, and Sub-Saharan Africa. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y represent themajority in South Central Asia (75 %) and Sub-SaharanAfrica (75 %) and just under half of all Chinese(47 %). Together the poor in these three z<strong>on</strong>escomprise 70 percent of the global poor. 36Dire C<strong>on</strong>sequences and Missed DevelopmentOpportunitiesWithout en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable property rights, residents ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements are often subject to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cefulevicti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y must fend <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themselves or paybribes to local landlords to defend their right tooccupy land, protect it from harmful encroachment,and settle disputes. Lack of protecti<strong>on</strong>,of tenure and of legal leverage <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivity, decreases productivity. It leads to socialexclusi<strong>on</strong>, reproduced over generati<strong>on</strong>s and visiblein the spatial segregati<strong>on</strong> of the poor in theurban housing envir<strong>on</strong>ment. Envir<strong>on</strong>mental andbehavioural degradati<strong>on</strong> is closely linked to thevicious circles perpetuated by faltering propertyrights systems which fail the poor and slow downthe development of society at large. Residents inextra-legal settlements have no legitimate way totransfer a home to a family member or heir nor torent or sell to another. Illegal black land marketsemerge and abusive practices become prevalent.Due to a lack of property rights guarantee, manyassets in developing nati<strong>on</strong>s are not fungible. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>poor and their potential business partners haveno criteria to establish or realise the potential oftheir assets. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no clear reciprocity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> holdingeach other accountable and no sufficient ba-76


sis to protect transacti<strong>on</strong>s or to pool assets withothers. For the nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omy, extra-legalitysets off a cycle of disinvestment in housing; itrepresents a lost opportunity to stimulate productiveec<strong>on</strong>omic activity.Rural Poverty and Property RightsDespite c<strong>on</strong>tinuing urbanisati<strong>on</strong>, two-thirdsof the poor live in rural areas. Ninety-fivepercent live in China, South Central Asia and SubSaharan Africa. Together these rural poor account<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> around half the world’s total poor.Rural Land Relati<strong>on</strong>s and Extreme PovertyInsufficient land to live <strong>on</strong>, and insecure accessor rights over land, are well recognised factors insustaining poverty. 38 Rural landlessness is oftenthe best predictor of extreme poverty and hunger.Inadequate rights regarding land often result inentrenched poverty and are significant impedimentsto rural development and to alleviati<strong>on</strong> ofhunger. 39 Eliminati<strong>on</strong> of the causes of tenure insecurityis thus imperative <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fighting poverty.Rural Land Relati<strong>on</strong>s and Armed C<strong>on</strong>fl ictC<strong>on</strong>flict over rural land ownership and accessis almost always near the centre of armed civilc<strong>on</strong>flict. 40 With various degrees of prominence,war over land access has been a driver, such asbetween the land rights of farmers and pastoralists(Burkina Faso), citizens and strangers (Côted’Ivoire), indigenous and proto-col<strong>on</strong>ial groups(Namibia, Liberia, Mozambique), and ethnicgroups (Rwanda, Burundi, Sudan, Uganda). Essentially,it is about c<strong>on</strong>flicts of interest — andlegal rights — between the rural rich and ruralpoor. Not surprisingly, attenti<strong>on</strong> to the legalrights of the majority of poor is often an earlyplat<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of post-c<strong>on</strong>flict re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, most recentlyin Sudan and Liberia, 41 quite aside from theneed to address c<strong>on</strong>flict-induced land losses andoccupati<strong>on</strong>s. 42Natural ResourcesLand is not the <strong>on</strong>ly aspect of rural property disorder.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> majority of rural poor depend up<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests, pastures and swamplands. Forests al<strong>on</strong>eaccount <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 3.8 billi<strong>on</strong> hectares, of which <strong>on</strong>ebilli<strong>on</strong> grow in Asia and Africa, the two poorestregi<strong>on</strong>s. 43 Issues of who legally owns theseresources, the land <strong>on</strong> which they grow, and towhom the rental (c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>) and product valuesaccrue is an urgent c<strong>on</strong>cern of the rural poor. 44As the tenure and benefit share of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eshore andseedbed resources, fish-rich swamplands and(especially near-surface) minerals all deliver milli<strong>on</strong>sof dollars annually to n<strong>on</strong>-customary ownersand, notably, to governments, there are ownershipissues to be c<strong>on</strong>sidered.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> importance of water rights and their relati<strong>on</strong>to land rights is likely to increase. Already today,close to <strong>on</strong>e third of the world’s populati<strong>on</strong> sufferfrom moderate to high water shortage. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Water estimates that the demand<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> water will increase by around 50 percent inthe next 30 years and that around 4 billi<strong>on</strong> peoplewill live in severe c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of water shortage by2025. 45 Increased pressure <strong>on</strong> water resources isa result of populati<strong>on</strong> increase as well as ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> value of land and real property oftendepends directly <strong>on</strong> the existence of adequate waterrights. In this situati<strong>on</strong> property rights definingwho has access to water will play a key role. Decisi<strong>on</strong>sabout water rights will become increasinglyimportant with direct impact <strong>on</strong> rights and opportunitiesc<strong>on</strong>cerning the use of land. 46Women Especially AffectedWomen own less than 10 percent of the world’sproperty: 47 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y c<strong>on</strong>stitute half the world’s popu-77


Table 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rural poor in the poorest regi<strong>on</strong>s of the world(Populati<strong>on</strong> figures in milli<strong>on</strong>s)Poorest Regi<strong>on</strong>sof the World**TotalPopulati<strong>on</strong>2005Percentdefinedas poor*Number ofpoor 2005Percent inrural areasEst. number ofrural poorSub Saharan Africa 752 75 564 66 372South Central Asia 1615 75 1211 70 848China 1304 47 613 63 386North Africa 194 29 56 53 30Latin America and Caribbean 559 26 145 24 35Eastern Europe 297 14 42 32 134,721 56 2,631 64 1,684* Excludes Europe, Oceania, North America, etc.** <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Populati<strong>on</strong> Reference Bureau uses the internati<strong>on</strong>ally-recognised criteri<strong>on</strong> of living <strong>on</strong> less than $2 a day as the measure of poverty.lati<strong>on</strong>, they produce between 60 and 80 percentof the food in developing countries, and they areresp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rural households in increasingnumbers. Much of the misery in the developingworld is due to statutory and customary propertysystems which disenfranchise women. 48 Wherewomen have property rights, they often comein ‘thin bundles’ as compared with men. 49 Toofrequently women face barriers to owning, using,and transferring or inheriting property. Womenface <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cible evicti<strong>on</strong> from their homes and theirland (over which they had customary or otherrights) by family members, traditi<strong>on</strong>al authoritiesand/or neighbours. 50 Property grabbing exacerbatesurbanisati<strong>on</strong> trends, sending more womento in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements and slums from urbanareas. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> problem is intertwined with that ofinheritance, as many widows are evicted fromland and property. Barriers exist de jure if statutesor regulati<strong>on</strong>s prohibit women from using,owing, or inheriting property. Enacting <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallaws that provide a woman with property rightsdoes not necessarily mean that she will be able toexercise her rights. Often, barriers to the exerciseof property rights are found to exist de facto, inc<strong>on</strong>sequence of poor en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal rightsor of social norms.Creating en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable property rights is essentialto empower women in both ruraland urban settings. 51 Women who own propertyor otherwise c<strong>on</strong>trol assets directly gain fromsuch benefits as use of the land and higher incomesas well as having a secure place to live. 52Empowering women with property rights does agreat deal to alleviate poverty and malnutriti<strong>on</strong>,as women who earn more spend a higher proporti<strong>on</strong>of their income to keep their children healthyand well-fed. 53 Providing women with the right touse, own, and transfer moveable and immovableproperty is important to promote entrepreneurialactivity and to provide women with a plat<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>building str<strong>on</strong>g families and str<strong>on</strong>g businesses.Indigenous PeoplesDefiniti<strong>on</strong> of Indigenous Peoples Has Yet to ReachSatisfactory Maturati<strong>on</strong>: Indigenous peoplesdistinguish themselves by being historically, socially,ec<strong>on</strong>omically, instituti<strong>on</strong>ally and politicallymarginalized. That they are usually 54 a minority78


in their countries is added reas<strong>on</strong> to take specialsteps to ensure that their interests are not ignored.Indigenous peoples are generally described asnumbering around 300-370 milli<strong>on</strong> people withinup to 5,000 distinctive groups. In June 2006, theUN Human Rights Council adopted <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Declarati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> the Rights of Indigenous Peoples, draftingof which had begun in the 1980s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> definiti<strong>on</strong>of indigenous peoples has seen repeated amendment55 and remains c<strong>on</strong>tested, particularly <strong>on</strong> theAfrican c<strong>on</strong>tinent. This was a factor in the failureof the Declarati<strong>on</strong> to meet UN General Assemblyapproval in November 2006.Focus <strong>on</strong> Indigenous Tenure SystemsMany indigenous lands have been and still aredeclared public or unoccupied because they areheld collectively according to c<strong>on</strong>cepti<strong>on</strong>s ofownership and access that do not fit well withimported property systems. This lack of statushas c<strong>on</strong>sequences <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenous asset holdersand society at large and is a critical issue, globally,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property rights re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. In addressingproblems of land issues of indigenous peoplesaround the world, it is advantageous to focusup<strong>on</strong> indigenous land tenure systems rather than<strong>on</strong> the identificati<strong>on</strong> of indigenous people per se.This sidesteps the troubled definiti<strong>on</strong> as to whois and who is not ‘indigenous’ and has the addedadvantage of zeroing in <strong>on</strong> the systemic issues ofindigenous or customary tenure regimes.Where ethnic and indigenous minorities areidentified and territorially placed, it maybe unnecessary to belabour distincti<strong>on</strong>s betweenthe indigenous and their tenure systems. In suchcases, it is advisable to simply promote theirterritorial aut<strong>on</strong>omy and sovereignty. It shouldinclude their stewardship over natural resources,and extend to matters of property — and all withoutside interventi<strong>on</strong> kept to a minimum. Focus <strong>on</strong>indigenous or customary tenure systems is criticalin the two regi<strong>on</strong>s where the poor are most numerous— Sub-Saharan Africa and Central Asia— and where delimitati<strong>on</strong> and identificati<strong>on</strong> ofindigenous peoples is difficult and c<strong>on</strong>tested.Important Numbers of Customary Land HoldersCustomary land holders comprise roughly two billi<strong>on</strong>people in Africa, South East and South CentralAsia and Latin America and the Caribbean.Given that around 80 percent of these rural dwellersare defined as ‘poor’ — i.e., living <strong>on</strong>Table 3 Main Regi<strong>on</strong>s Where Customary Land Tenure Operates(Populati<strong>on</strong> figures are in milli<strong>on</strong>s)Regi<strong>on</strong>sPopulati<strong>on</strong>2005percentRuralNumberRuralpercentdefinedas poor*Numberof poor2005Number ofrural poorSub Saharan Africa 752 66 496 75 564 372North Africa 194 53 103 29 56 30South Central Asia 1615 70 1130 75 1211 848South East Asia 557 62 345 56 312 345Latin America and Caribbean 559 24 134 26 145 353,677 60 2,208 71 2,288 1,630Source of base fi gures: Populati<strong>on</strong> Census Bureau, 2005. 5679


under US$2 a day standard — then 1.6 billi<strong>on</strong>people may be defined as ‘the customary poor’.Refugees, Internally DisplacedPers<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> disorder of property relati<strong>on</strong>s created byinternal or interstate c<strong>on</strong>flict deserves specialattenti<strong>on</strong>. 57 Putting property relati<strong>on</strong>s backin order or providing adequate compensati<strong>on</strong> tovictims is at the heart of sustainable peace building.58 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> situati<strong>on</strong> becomes more dramatic whennatural disasters strike. In recent memory, thenumbers displaced by the three major disasterssince the end of 2004 (the tsunamis of 26 December2004, Hurricane Katrina of 29 August2005, and the earthquake of 8 October 2005 innorthern Pakistan and adjoining areas in Indiaand Afghanistan), is around 2 milli<strong>on</strong>, accordingto the Representative of the UN Secretary-General<strong>on</strong> the human rights of internally displacedpers<strong>on</strong>s. 59 Given the fact of global warming, andthe increasing number of natural disasters, thenumber of displaced pers<strong>on</strong>s falling into uncertainproperty relati<strong>on</strong>s is likely to grow. Also,empowerment of the poor through property rightshas to be seen as most urgent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> orderly reestablishmentof property relati<strong>on</strong>s after disastersand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the development of reliable insuranceschemes. 60 Hurricane Katrina victims had propertyrights and insurance schemes that mitigatedtheir losses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poorest people of the world lackand desperately need such securities.3. Barriers versusFacilitators of Change<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is evidence of enormous social and ec<strong>on</strong>omicpotential in the establishment of propertyrights systems <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all societies. 61 This insightleads to the questi<strong>on</strong> as to what actors and structuralbarriers prevent societies from adopting generallybeneficial property rights systems and whatcan be d<strong>on</strong>e to overcome these barriers.Resistance of Powerful SocialActorsPrivate owners of illegally occupied propertyoften resist allocating land to squatters againstmarket value compensati<strong>on</strong>. 62 Some businessactors profiting from m<strong>on</strong>opoly-like positi<strong>on</strong>s wantto avoid competiti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y resist legalisati<strong>on</strong>and undermine good governance. 63 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>yers andnotaries profit from the complexity of legal propertysystems excluding the poor. 64 State officialsprofit from bureaucratic complexity of the systemthrough gatekeeping and briberies. Entrepreneursin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector refrain from registeringbusinesses and property to avoid taxes and costlyregulati<strong>on</strong>s. 65Structural Obstacles andFacilitators of ChangeActors tackling the task of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m also have tobe aware of structural causes of stagnati<strong>on</strong> orchange. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> distributi<strong>on</strong> of power plays an importantrole in determining the likelihood of theemergence of fair property rights systems. Landand income distributi<strong>on</strong> is another factor in thisregard. Indeed, it has been shown that the natureof the prevailing political regime and land andincome inequality are important determinants ofproperty rights structure. 66 When political power80


is c<strong>on</strong>centrated in the hands of the few, and/orland and income distributi<strong>on</strong> is skewed resultingin extreme inequality, political authorities areunlikely to implement and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce property rightsin an equitable manner. 67 This indicates that theevoluti<strong>on</strong> of property rights systems is to a largeextent determined by historical c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, suchas the distributi<strong>on</strong> of factors of producti<strong>on</strong>. 68Realising TurnaroundUnderstanding the likely impact of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms <strong>on</strong>n<strong>on</strong>-poor groups with significant influenceis critical to assess potential support and oppositi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. 69 Besides promoting pro-poorproperty rights it is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e important to establishproperty rights systems that are beneficial<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> middle classes and groups with significantassets and political influence. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> message to allis that in the absence of generalised and equitableproperty rights systems much of ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivity does not develop its full potential even<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> powerful actors 70 ; there is a high likelihood ofsocial unrest 71 ; there may be under-accumulati<strong>on</strong>of human capital resulting in a low quality labour<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce, and little demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit resulting in underdevelopedfinancial instituti<strong>on</strong>s and ultimatelyhindered growth. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is also less <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign investmentor flight of capital when property rights arenot guaranteed.scenario. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> emergence of property rights andthe distributi<strong>on</strong> of resources may have mutualcausal effect. 73 Examples of countries like Chinaand Singapore teach us that an alternative routeof political authorities c<strong>on</strong>senting to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms isa possibility where inequalities are less extreme.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> issue of better understanding how to devisemechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>vincing the political authoritiesor circumventing their influence in orderto induce the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m c<strong>on</strong>stitutes an importantchallenge. An important implicati<strong>on</strong> of this viewis that a drastic <strong>on</strong>e-time re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m may have l<strong>on</strong>glasting c<strong>on</strong>sequences, setting the process of everimproving distributi<strong>on</strong> al<strong>on</strong>g side with more equitableproperty rights systems.Provided that inequalities are not too extreme,equitable property rights may emerge preciselybecause of their beneficial c<strong>on</strong>sequences <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>groups with significant assets and political influence.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y may also emerge out of the desireof elites to avoid adverse c<strong>on</strong>sequences fromexceeding numbers of poor people not havingaccess to property rights. 72 Indeed, several recentexamples in Asia, where political leadersinduced progressive re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, including equitableproperty rights, are illustrative of precisely this81


4. Learning from the PastLearning from previous re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms in view of improvingpractices carries c<strong>on</strong>siderable burdens of judgmentas <strong>on</strong>e tries to measure the possible applicabilityof particular less<strong>on</strong>s to future re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms in very differentc<strong>on</strong>texts. What is provided in this secti<strong>on</strong> isa compressed selecti<strong>on</strong> of less<strong>on</strong>s to give actors <strong>on</strong>the ground better c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s to reach their own in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>medjudgment.Problematic Practices and Omissi<strong>on</strong>sSix general less<strong>on</strong>s from past mistakes arepresented as follows:1) Disregarding that effective property rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor are the result of power relati<strong>on</strong>s andsystemic interacti<strong>on</strong>. Many ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to give thepoor effective and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable property rightshave focused <strong>on</strong> necessary technical and legalissues at the expense of paying attenti<strong>on</strong>to how power relati<strong>on</strong>s influence the propertyrights system in its impact <strong>on</strong> the most vulnerablemembers of society. This has hinderedeffective realisati<strong>on</strong> of theoretically anticipatedre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. Associati<strong>on</strong>alpower of the poor, more symmetric in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>,legal literacy, procedural assistance andinstituti<strong>on</strong>al capacity building are as importantas the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal instruments of propertyrights. 742) Failing to assess the credit market envir<strong>on</strong>mentof the property system and assumingthat credit markets will evolve automaticallyfrom property rights. In general, rates of mortgagingremain very low in developing countries,partly due to low demand, partly due toavailability of less risky alternative sources ofloans than possible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eclosure threatens andin the past partly due to low values in a market.75 Given the reluctance of banks to destroythe entire livelihood of a poor family in theevent of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eclosure and the likelihood of localresistance to attempts to take or sell off thecollateralised property, there is limited accessto mortgages and credit, especially in ruralareas. 76 Understanding the role of credit marketsin relati<strong>on</strong> to property rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>has led to some important shifts in d<strong>on</strong>or landpolicies in recent years. It is now acceptedthat <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> markets to move land and real propertyto the poor in a sustainable manner targetedcredit must be provided.3) Assuming that the state is str<strong>on</strong>g and trustworthyand that there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e property titles and registriesas well as the guarantee of transacti<strong>on</strong>sare reliable and corrupti<strong>on</strong> proof. 77 In manycountries land administrati<strong>on</strong> is <strong>on</strong>e of themost corrupt public services. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most egregiousexamples include irregularities and outrightfraud in allocating and managing publiclands. Even petty corrupti<strong>on</strong> in regular servicedelivery can involve large sums and have farreachingec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>sequences. 784) Failure to include moveable property andshareholder schemes of ownership and valueadditi<strong>on</strong> in policies promoting property rights.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> asset base of the poor can be extended byinnovative <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of n<strong>on</strong>-real estate and n<strong>on</strong>creditbased corporate shareholder ownershipand by using moveable property as collateral.Unlike land and housing, the reproductivepotential of n<strong>on</strong>-tangible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of property ispotentially unlimited.5) Repressing Opportunities al<strong>on</strong>gside with Risk.Even a moderate increase in the liberties andentitlements that come with private property,be it owned by individuals or groups, can oftencreate c<strong>on</strong>siderable benefits. 79 Thin bundlesof property rights, reducing the fungibility of82


property, c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the exclusi<strong>on</strong> of the poorfrom the chain of value additi<strong>on</strong> in case of landdevelopment, compensati<strong>on</strong> payments, andgeneral increase of property value. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> risksof the land and financial market have invitedspecial policy measures which are supposedto protect the poor from predators and harmfulmarket <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces. Such practices mainly includec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming collectives in orderto register property under a single legal entity,restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the right to transfer (moratoria)after land privatisati<strong>on</strong> or titling, quantitativeceilings of ownership, special qualificati<strong>on</strong> toprofit from land and real estate redistributi<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> incentives to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m collectives are beneficialwhere they are related to and protectexisting communal structures. 80 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are oftendysfuncti<strong>on</strong>al in c<strong>on</strong>texts where a majority or avery active minority of people wants to act asindividuals or small family groups and wherethe moratoria are too l<strong>on</strong>g and time is notused <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> capacity building. 816) Failure to c<strong>on</strong>ceive gender equitable propertyrights systems. In many countries, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malstatutory law operates in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with customarylaw and cultural norms and practicesbased <strong>on</strong> patriarchal attitudes which makeit difficult to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce women’s legal rights toland as wives and daughters. Individualisticstatutory law favouring the male householdhead and customary practices and hierarchiescombine into a mix that is harmful <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women.Where customary law and more gender c<strong>on</strong>sciencestatutory law c<strong>on</strong>flict, oftentimes thecustomary law trumps. In some instancesstatutory law has erased customary practicesfavouring widows or women in general. <strong>Legal</strong>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m does not improve the precarious propertyrights situati<strong>on</strong> of women if there are noen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement mechanisms, and if legal assistanceand support services are not af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dableor accessible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women. 82Less<strong>on</strong>s from mistakes related to land and realproperty:1) Failure to address the problem of landlessnessand extremely unequal land distributi<strong>on</strong>.Market based re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms are not the definitesoluti<strong>on</strong> to this problem, but land purchaseand redistributi<strong>on</strong> of underused land by thestate, multilateral d<strong>on</strong>ors or land-banks byprivate foundati<strong>on</strong>s can avoid the social unrestand withdrawal of private investment usuallycaused by compulsory acquisiti<strong>on</strong> and expropriati<strong>on</strong>.832) Retaining that customary tenure and interestsin comm<strong>on</strong>s does not represent private propertyrights in and of themselves and are there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>enot eligible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registrati<strong>on</strong> without c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong>into imported <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. 84 Sustaining versi<strong>on</strong>s ofcollective assets in particular as ‘un-ownedland’ or default state-owned, instead of registeringthese as the private, group-owned propertyof communities has deprived milli<strong>on</strong>s of poorof a secure asset and income base. Customarytenure systems were thought to provide insufficienttenure security. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y were assumed toimpede farmers from making necessary investmentsin land and they were associated withthe ‘tragedy of the comm<strong>on</strong>s.’ 85 Research hasshown that such systems can be effective. Bydefault and notwithstanding important qualificati<strong>on</strong>s,customary tenure systems are to bec<strong>on</strong>sidered as providing an adequate framework<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> private group-owned property. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y havebeen flexible and resp<strong>on</strong>sive to changing ec<strong>on</strong>omiccircumstances. 86 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y limit the propertyrights bundle to a specific group of people asthe bearers of those rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> household, thevillage, and the kin group often provide insur-83


ance against risks, access to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal credit,and security. Lineage rules of inheritance helpen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce intergenerati<strong>on</strong>al transfers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> threatof social exclusi<strong>on</strong> is a major instrument ofen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of the rules. In other words, essentialfuncti<strong>on</strong>s of the property rights systemare fulfilled by customary systems and ought tobe legally rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced. 873) Assuming high demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entitlement,i.e. assuming that rural and remote landholdersfelt their rights to their house and farmplots are threatened or that they explicitlywant to raise loans <strong>on</strong> the basis of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal titlesto these assets. 88 Paying insufficient attenti<strong>on</strong>to the time and financial costs of titling,to both government and landholder. 89 In particularassuming that titling always has to becadastre-based and rest up<strong>on</strong> expensive surveyand mapping. 904) Assuming that titling is the prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>property security when other measures offermore immediate and simpler ways of securingthe assets of the poor, especially in remote ruralareas. Even in rural African c<strong>on</strong>texts, whereindividual titling of land may not be desirableor feasible and the use of land as collateral <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>credit is <strong>on</strong>ly a remote possibility, providingpoor land owners or users with documentedrights can yield significant benefits. 915) Failing to pay attenti<strong>on</strong> to pro-poor land marketdevelopment and failing to assess the impactof the land market <strong>on</strong> the poor. 926) Failure to Simplify Land Administrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Least Advantaged Customer. In manycountries, land administrati<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>s aredispersed am<strong>on</strong>g many Ministries (justice,envir<strong>on</strong>ment, agriculture, urban, finance, landre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>est, mining, etc.). This createsgrey z<strong>on</strong>es of overlapping competencies as abreeding ground <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-transparent practices.Even if resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities are clearly assignedand overlaps avoided, this creates c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong>am<strong>on</strong>g users, prevents realisati<strong>on</strong> of ec<strong>on</strong>omiesof scale, and thus increases the cost ofproviding land administrati<strong>on</strong> services to thedetriment of the poor. 937) Failing to Restrict Eminent Domain. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reshould be a strict focus <strong>on</strong> using eminentdomain as ultima ratio in providing essentialpublic services rather than as a means toimprove general public utility. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> latter promotesillegitimate alliances of state ownershipand powerful particular interest and severelydamages the property rights of marginal landusers by excluding them from adequate compensati<strong>on</strong>or inclusi<strong>on</strong> in chains of value additi<strong>on</strong>through property development.8) Insufficient Revenue Sharing in Gains fromNatural Resources. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re has been lack of attenti<strong>on</strong>to the possibility of community basednatural resource management in the case of<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests, fishery, and water. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re has beeninsufficient participati<strong>on</strong> of citizens in therevenues from the extracti<strong>on</strong>, treatment, anddistributi<strong>on</strong> of natural resources.Experienced C<strong>on</strong>sequences1) Enduring extra-legality of the majority of assetholders despite existing property systems andtitling programmes is a persisting phenomen<strong>on</strong>.It is due to imperfect implementati<strong>on</strong>in some cases but in many other settings it isthe result of a mismatch of official instituti<strong>on</strong>sand local practices.2) Disrupti<strong>on</strong> of Existing Tenurial Arrangements.Careless implementati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal documentati<strong>on</strong>may have the effect of inadvertentlydisrupting existing tenurial arrangements.84


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re may be sound policy reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> seekingto modify or eliminate some existing tenurialpractices. It is important, however, that anysuch re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms are the result of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med andparticipatory decisi<strong>on</strong>-making, and not theinadvertent result of poorly designed or implementedtitling processes.3) C<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> and Discriminati<strong>on</strong>. In manycountries, including the countries of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merSoviet Uni<strong>on</strong>, it has been observed that somepeople may be less well positi<strong>on</strong>ed to participateeffectively in the documentati<strong>on</strong> and registrati<strong>on</strong>process than others, with the effect thattheir rights are poorly protected. Individualswho loose in such c<strong>on</strong>texts are usually women,absentee right holders or mortgagees, and ingeneral people with less educati<strong>on</strong> and limitedaccess to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> becoming victim to manipulati<strong>on</strong>and fraud.4) Increase in Disputes. Registrati<strong>on</strong> of landis expected to reduce the incidence of landdisputes, by clarifying boundaries, by resolvingambiguities about rights over land and byputting in place a registrati<strong>on</strong> system that istransparent, reliable and accessible. In theshort term, however, the process of adjudicati<strong>on</strong>and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of rights may bringto the surface latent disputes that may haveotherwise remained below the surface. Suchpotential risk needs to be assessed in theplanning phase of a re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m project.5) Capitalisati<strong>on</strong>: Difficult <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor in Absenceof Adequate Land and Capital Markets.State of the art analysis reveals <strong>on</strong>ly a modestpositive effect of land titling <strong>on</strong> access tomortgage credit, and no impact <strong>on</strong> access toother <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of credit. It shows no effect <strong>on</strong> thelabour income of the households holding newtitles. However, it is shown that moving a poorhousehold from uncertain usufructuary rightsto a more complete bundle of property rightssubstantially increased investment in the familyhouses. Property registrati<strong>on</strong> and guaranteeof the homes reduced the size of families andthese smaller families invested more in theeducati<strong>on</strong> of their children. Another study findsthat <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal property rights lead to more availabletime <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> productive activities of propertyholders who do no l<strong>on</strong>ger need to defend theirassets. 94Property rights bring increased ec<strong>on</strong>omic benefitswhen linked to a functi<strong>on</strong>al credit systemand market, but they do not, by themselves,cause the emergence of a functi<strong>on</strong>al and propoorcredit system. 95 <strong>Legal</strong> property rights effectivelylead to credit and investment whererobust financial markets exist and where thereare further incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> investment. 96 Evenwhen in possessi<strong>on</strong> of titles and registeredproperty, small-scale farmers and the urbanpoor most often do not put their land or modestdwellings at risk by using them as collateral<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit. 97 Tenure security and ec<strong>on</strong>omicbenefits other than capitalisati<strong>on</strong> via collateralof land property seem to be primordial <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor. Although they are efficient producers,small-scale farmers and business peopletend to lose out in land and financial marketswhich are regulated with provisi<strong>on</strong>s that privilegec<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong>. Market based land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msthere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e now tend to be accompanied withtargeted credit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor.6) Costs and Benefits of Property Rights Protecti<strong>on</strong>.From the perspective of the poor andthe state, the costs of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal titles have tobe weighed against the costs of insecurity oftenure, or against in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal costs (bribes) inobtaining titles which harm the poor and thestate. 98 In many unre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med c<strong>on</strong>texts, <strong>on</strong>ly few85


households can af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d the cost of a title. 99 Aswill be discussed, adapting laws and proceduresto the social c<strong>on</strong>text can c<strong>on</strong>siderablyreduce the costs of titling and registrati<strong>on</strong>by reducing administrative inefficiencies andby the use of modern technology. <strong>Legal</strong>ly en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cedproperty rights systems are not necessarilycost ineffective and expensive. 1007) Fees and Taxes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> integrati<strong>on</strong> of irregularsettlements into legal property rights systemsincreases tax revenues to governments. 101 Onthe other hand it is obvious that inappropriatefees and taxes can push people back into extralegality.102 As far as the poor are c<strong>on</strong>cerned,registrati<strong>on</strong> fees and taxes have to be set atminimal levels. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> key elements that have tobe in place <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property tax re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m: existence ofadequate technical expertise; appropriate landrecords and administrati<strong>on</strong> are required as thebasis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the property lists; sufficient flexibilityto allow the phasing in of major changes is essentialto <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>estall challenges and resistance tochanges; political understanding and will areperhaps the most critical prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s if thesubstantial challenges of implementing a highlyvisible, difficult to evade, tax, are to be overcome.1035. Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and ImprovedActi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> diversity of c<strong>on</strong>texts and stakeholders affectedby problems of faltering property rights,as well as the high complexity of the issue, doesnot indicate that there will be a <strong>on</strong>e time, <strong>on</strong>esize-fits-allsoluti<strong>on</strong>. What is needed is a seriousand c<strong>on</strong>tinuously m<strong>on</strong>itored re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process andparallel interventi<strong>on</strong>s inducing far-reaching andsustainable re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of the four building blocks ofthe property rights system; that is: (1) re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mingthe property system as <strong>on</strong>e of rules defining orenabling bundles and bearers of property rightsallowing the poor to access and secure propertyal<strong>on</strong>e, as members of communities, or as communities;(2) re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming it as a system of governanceso that targeted acti<strong>on</strong>s securing the propertyrights of the poor can be taken effectively and legitimately;(3) re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming it as a functi<strong>on</strong>ing marketof assets to include the poor in the chains ofvalue additi<strong>on</strong> enabling them to become capablemarket participants, and (4) re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the propertysystem as <strong>on</strong>e of social policy with targetedmeasures of capacity building, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, andaccess to property and housing. Parallel re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mwork sustained by c<strong>on</strong>stant m<strong>on</strong>itoring in all fourdimensi<strong>on</strong>s is advocated to achieve real progress.Comm<strong>on</strong> features of policy design and prioritisingare also dealt with in this secti<strong>on</strong>, and outlinesare presented of important subsidiary and stabilisingacti<strong>on</strong>s that either have or can be taken byd<strong>on</strong>or countries and multilateral organisati<strong>on</strong>s.86Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming Rules Regarding Bearersand Bundles of Property RightsProperty rights stand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the bundle of libertiesand claim rights tied to the allocati<strong>on</strong> of a resourceto a natural or legal pers<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> property


system as a system of rules regarding the bundlesand bearers of property rights determineswho can legally own property, what is recognisedas property and what can be d<strong>on</strong>e with property.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s should promote rather than limit ordiscriminate against bearers of property rights;they should allow freedom to bestow sufficientlythick bundles of property rights <strong>on</strong> individuals orgroups and should not unduly limit the scope ofcreative activity that can be invested in property.Individual and comm<strong>on</strong> Private PropertyPromote Individual and Corporate <strong>Legal</strong> Identity;Limited Corporate Liability. Property law shouldoffer clear and simple opti<strong>on</strong>s of legal pers<strong>on</strong>alityand corporate ownership <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> small businessesand corporative associati<strong>on</strong>s of the poor. <strong>Legal</strong>pers<strong>on</strong>ality so designed opens a range of possibilitiesof ownership by individuals, membersof collectives, and by collectives. A legal pers<strong>on</strong>can hold property as an individual, but the definiti<strong>on</strong>of a legal pers<strong>on</strong> can also be extended toa collective or comm<strong>on</strong> property of a myriad ofmembers, who in turn may own some propertyrights individually. Pro-poor property rights systemsfacilitate the ability of people to pool andleverage modest resources and limit liabilities incase of business failure or exit of partners. Onekey to ec<strong>on</strong>omic success <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> small entrepreneursin the developing world is the limited liability ofbusiness owners, allowing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trolled failurewithout disastrous c<strong>on</strong>sequences <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the vulnerableindividuals involved. This legal instrument oflimited corporate liability has to be extended tothe poor micro entrepreneurs and rural producersin the developing world in a simple, straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>wardmanner. Its main advantage is <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality ofbusiness ownership that trumps disadvantages of<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality such as tariffs and taxes, provided theseare af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable.Promote Associati<strong>on</strong>al Property Structures. Housingand land associati<strong>on</strong>s prove how individualand comm<strong>on</strong> property can be combined to favourpeople with limited assets without disenfranchisingthem to a collectivity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> associati<strong>on</strong>, aslegal pers<strong>on</strong>, is owner of the real property andcollectively resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> mortgage loans, givingthe associati<strong>on</strong> more leverage in negotiatingloans and public services. Members, however, gettradable rights to plots, houses or apartments,and c<strong>on</strong>tribute to repayment of the overall loanthrough m<strong>on</strong>thly rent. Apartments or plots areincreasingly sold at open market prices, but associati<strong>on</strong>members have pre-empti<strong>on</strong> rights toenter into the agreement at an agreed price. 104<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> idea is to provide a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of ownership to balancethe interests of the individual or family withthose of a broader community. With this purpose,Australia introduced Strata Title in 1961 to bettercope with apartment blocks. Other countries haveadopted the Australian system of apartment ownership,including Canada, Singapore, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia,Malaysia, Fiji and the Philippines, and still othershave successfully created their own schemes.Strata title is not <strong>on</strong>ly applicable to vertical livingbut also to cluster living in slums. In many developingc<strong>on</strong>texts, there has been a tendency <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>law to prescribe in too much detail the structureof local organisati<strong>on</strong>s and the rules by which theycan operate. At the same time, injecting greater<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and accountability into local organisati<strong>on</strong>sis obviously important.Simplified Property Rights Certificati<strong>on</strong>. Somecountries have adopted simple, locally administeredprocesses to c<strong>on</strong>fer legal land rights asalternatives to c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al land titling. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y arepractical, inclusive, benefiting growing populati<strong>on</strong>sof the rural poor, 105 and are being increasinglyused to enhance urban land tenure security.106 As many require no prior physical planning,87


Box 2 Acquiring property rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poorIn Pakistan, incremental expansi<strong>on</strong> of urban servicesallowed c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements (katchiabadis) in Hyderabad into legal housing neighbourhoods.In Trinidad and Tobago these alternativeinstruments have the advantage of being part of anincremental process of acquiring secure tenure. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re,the State Land (Regularisati<strong>on</strong> of Tenure) <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> of 1998paved the way <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> progressive issue of Certificates ofCom<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t, Statutory Leases and Deeds of Lease to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsettlers <strong>on</strong> state land. A similar model has beenunder development in Namibia since the late 1990sand proposes a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum comprising Starter, Landholdand Freehold titles. In Brazil, the usucapião is a<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of adverse possessi<strong>on</strong> over private land, so thereis no need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> authorities to issue a title: the judicialsentence declaring that a new real right over the landhas been c<strong>on</strong>stituted over time is the legal documentnecessary to promote land registrati<strong>on</strong> and ownershiptransfer. This can be d<strong>on</strong>e individually or collectively,and people get freehold rights either individually orin a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of co-ownership. It is a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of prescriptiveacquisiti<strong>on</strong>, a real right (in the legal sense), and nottemporary. It can be sold, inherited, etc., and there isno reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> banks not to accept it (Fernandes 2005).In India it is comm<strong>on</strong> practice to issue pattas givingrights to the poor over government land. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> patta, adocument issued by the Land Revenue Department,may be freehold or leasehold (99/30/10/1yr), renewableor not. It specifies c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> use, transfer andinheritance, and may be used to regularise occupati<strong>on</strong>or assign new plots. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> patta is usually given free ofcost, or with a small fee, and needs no registrati<strong>on</strong> toavail of rights specified. In states like Madhya Pradesh,Andhra Pradesh, Rajasthan and West Bengal, it canbe mortgaged against housing loans. If patta land isrequired <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> any ‘public purpose’, the holder has to beallotted alternate land. In Andhra Pradesh al<strong>on</strong>e, morethan 10 milli<strong>on</strong> pattas have been issued since 1962.(Banerjee 2006)infrastructure, or surveying, they offer widespreadcoverage at low cost, af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable by the poor.Recognising Customary Tenure and Communitiesas Bearers of Property Rights to Land and NaturalResourcesIndividual titling and/or alternative measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>incremental c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> of property claims areappropriate and beneficial in many urban c<strong>on</strong>texts.107 In rural c<strong>on</strong>texts, especially in Africa andparts of Asia, they need to be phased in from other<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of tenure security or replaced by new approachesto securing tenure to more fully cover thespectrum of the local ec<strong>on</strong>omic practices and c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1990s and early 2000s are repletewith examples of legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms in the directi<strong>on</strong> ofrecognising customary land rights (mainly in Africa,and notably in Tanzania, Uganda, Mozambiqueand some West African countries), and indigenousland rights (Philippines, Cambodia, Australia, anda number of countries in Latin America). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seinnovati<strong>on</strong>s come from different c<strong>on</strong>texts that maylimit comparability; nevertheless, <strong>on</strong>e can extractcomm<strong>on</strong> threads and identify comm<strong>on</strong> problemsthat will require attenti<strong>on</strong> in the years ahead. 108Broadly speaking, these laws share some of thefollowing characteristics or aspirati<strong>on</strong>s:• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y recognise that in many c<strong>on</strong>texts thesocial and ec<strong>on</strong>omic value of land is best realisedby allowing land relati<strong>on</strong>s to be governedby rules of the community in which the landis located, rather than by imposed systems ofproperty law.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y reflect a c<strong>on</strong>victi<strong>on</strong> that communitybasedtenure regimes are often better atproviding security of tenure to individual cultivators.Often, individual cultivators fear dis-88


Box 3 Namibian land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mIn Namibia, legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms in 1996 created a framework<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> community-based natural resource management(CBNRM). Namibians who <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m c<strong>on</strong>servanciesnow have legal rights to manage wildlife andto benefit from tourism. With these secured rights,rural Namibians have reduced levels of poaching,have seen wildlife numbers increase substantially,and are seeing their ecosystems rebounding. Arelated benefit is that rural Namibians now haveopportunities to pursue a new set of entrepreneurialventures. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are empowered to build businessesbased <strong>on</strong> eco-tourism and related activities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>sebusinesses help to diversify livelihoods and providevaluable benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>servancy members.Namibia’s experience with CBNRM may provide astr<strong>on</strong>g model <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> other countries: devolving securelegal rights to local people is promoting positiveoutcomes, both in terms of c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> and ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment. Source: Boudreaux 2007possessi<strong>on</strong> by government or outsiders, ratherthan by others within the community.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y acknowledge that community-basedsystems are also often better at reflecting thecomplex rights that individuals, families andgroups have over land, including sec<strong>on</strong>daryrights of access and use — rights that mightbe distorted or lost by titling according to astandardise <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mat that is not adapted to localrealities.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y recognise that a community’s relati<strong>on</strong>shipwith land is more than an aggregate ofindividually occupied plots: it is a system thatincludes natural resources used in comm<strong>on</strong>.Communal lands and comm<strong>on</strong> natural resources.Including grazing lands, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests, water, fisheries,in many poor countries are a special case of customarytenure and crucial <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the improvement ofthe legal and ec<strong>on</strong>omic status of the poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>yare vulnerable to degradati<strong>on</strong> and appropriati<strong>on</strong>by powerful chiefs, outsiders, or state bureaucratsunless comm<strong>on</strong> property resource managementsystems are rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced by legal sancti<strong>on</strong>.Increasing access to, and the locally beneficialproductivity of land and natural resources, can beachieved by:• Reaffirming and codifying customary rules inparticipatory ways, reflecting diversity in theethnic, historical, and social c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> ofland. Also setting legal boundaries, identifyingexisting rights that may overlap or be of a seas<strong>on</strong>alnature (e.g., between herders and sedentaryagriculturalists), and registering themas appropriate and orderly tradable.• Allowing communal land ownership as <strong>on</strong>elegal opti<strong>on</strong> and regular management decisi<strong>on</strong>sin an accountable body that functi<strong>on</strong>stransparently — <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, as an incorporateduser group — and having clear rules <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>c<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong> that are respected by allinvolved. Arriving at culturally appropriate legal<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> such bodies is key.• Ensuring that customary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of tenure canevolve towards more <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal types of tenurethrough well-defined and transparent processes,if and when, in the judgment of thosec<strong>on</strong>cerned, the benefits from more individualownership exceed the cost. 109<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> status of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal rights has come str<strong>on</strong>gly tothe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e. Most derive from, and are sustained by,community-based arrangements — i.e. indigenousor customary regimes. If inroads made thus farevolve and expand, some 400 milli<strong>on</strong> Africanscould benefit. No fewer than 40 milli<strong>on</strong> Ind<strong>on</strong>esians,or 40 milli<strong>on</strong> South Americans — andmilli<strong>on</strong>s of others globally — could also benefit,should comparable tentative shifts mature. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>89


implicati<strong>on</strong>s promise socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic changesnever quite achieved in previous re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms towardsredistributi<strong>on</strong>, collectivisati<strong>on</strong> or c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong>arytitling. Obviously, where states are too weak toc<strong>on</strong>trol local war and drug lords, devolving landownership or management to local communities isnot an opti<strong>on</strong> to empower the poor.Critical Issues in the Recogniti<strong>on</strong> of Customaryand Indigenous Tenure SystemsDrafting of laws that recognise customarytenure and that accommodate a numberof such tenure systems within a nati<strong>on</strong>al legalframework is a complex task. It is possible toidentify a number of challenges that are likely torequire attenti<strong>on</strong> from both drafters and implementers:Identifying Communities and Evolving Practices.State recogniti<strong>on</strong> of customary or communitybasedtenure requires identifying, with some degreeof precisi<strong>on</strong>, the community whose propertyrights are being recognised, the area over whichit has legitimate claims and the instituti<strong>on</strong>s ordecisi<strong>on</strong>-making processes whose decisi<strong>on</strong>s andoutcomes are entitled to respect by <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s. If carelessly d<strong>on</strong>e, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal recogniti<strong>on</strong>may have the effect of unduly privileging <strong>on</strong>e ofseveral competing local visi<strong>on</strong>s of what c<strong>on</strong>stitutesa community, and what rules or authoritiesare legitimate.Balancing Respect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Local Decisi<strong>on</strong>-makingwith Human Rights and Accountability. In somec<strong>on</strong>texts, custom may run c<strong>on</strong>trary to a visi<strong>on</strong> ofhuman rights enshrined in a nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>,particularly where it comes to the treatmentof women and minorities. A similar dilemmaarises when it comes to ensuring minimum levelsof accountability and transparency within customarystructures. However, customs are not rigidand unchanging. It is thus possible to aim at aprocess in which customary practices evolve inresp<strong>on</strong>se to social development and human rightsprinciples. 110Protecting Customary or Indigenous Rights whileEnhancing the Ability of Communities and IndividualHouseholds to Explore New Ec<strong>on</strong>omicOpportunities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no inherent c<strong>on</strong>tradicti<strong>on</strong>between giving increased legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> to customaryor indigenous tenure systems and promotingec<strong>on</strong>omic growth — indeed, in some c<strong>on</strong>textsit is argued that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer is a pre-requisite <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the latter. But the choice of legal techniques mayskew the balance between protecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>ehand and the ability to adapt to new opportunitiesor challenges <strong>on</strong> the other. Protecting theintegrity of local systems against the incursi<strong>on</strong>s ofricher and more sophisticated outsiders may, asa starting point, justify short-term restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>the alienability of land. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong> is whetheremphasis <strong>on</strong> protecti<strong>on</strong> reflects the needs and aspirati<strong>on</strong>sof local people in rapidly changing ec<strong>on</strong>omicenvir<strong>on</strong>ments. Some laws provide avenues<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> communities or individuals to attract outsideinvestment <strong>on</strong> their land, subject to an internalprocess of approval. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are in some cases opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals or groups to ‘opt out’ oflocal tenure systems in favour of acquiring individualisedtitles under a state-sp<strong>on</strong>sored scheme.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Challenge of Capacity and C<strong>on</strong>flict. Devolvinggreater authority to local instituti<strong>on</strong>s — whethertraditi<strong>on</strong>al bodies or local governments — has itsjustificati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong> to be asked in eachcase, however, is whether specific re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms assumethe existence of greater capacities at variouspoints in the system than in fact exist, or canbe expected to exist in the near future. In manyc<strong>on</strong>texts, c<strong>on</strong>flict-ridden areas will not allow<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> community based land and natural resourcemanagement and require tighter central c<strong>on</strong>trol.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> challenge of capacity and c<strong>on</strong>flict extends90


Box 4 Focus AfricaCustomary rights may now be registered without c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong>into introduced <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms in Uganda, Tanzaniaand Mozambique; the same is proposed in Lesotho,Malawi and Madagascar. Customary properties otherthan comm<strong>on</strong> properties may be registered in Namibiaand Botswana (since 1968). Although not defined ascustomary rights, given their aboliti<strong>on</strong> in 1975, existingoccupancy may also be registered ‘as is’ in Ethiopia.Customary rights in Mali, Niger, Burkina Faso, Benin,Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana and South Africa may be certificatedwith substantial effect, but with required or impliedc<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> into existing statutory <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms <strong>on</strong> final registrati<strong>on</strong>.Described incidents of customary rights reflect‘customary freehold’ and/or as customarily agreed bythe modern community. Most laws allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> customaryrights to be held in perpetuity, raising their statusabove that of leasehold or similar statutory <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mscomm<strong>on</strong> to most of Africa. Freehold is available mainlyin Southern Africa. Only Tanzania and Mozambiqueendow customary interests with unequivocal equivalencywith imported tenure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Uganda proclaimsthis but also provides <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> of customary certificates into freehold tenure. Lesotho and Malawi proposesomething similar. Mozambique does not practicewhat it preaches, giving investor interests in customarylands more support than customary interests.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> status of unregistered customary rights — morethan 90 percent of all rural landholding — is oftenambivalent and remains permissive, pending registrati<strong>on</strong>.Customary rights not registered are explicitly protectedin Uganda, Tanzania Mozambique and in a differentmanner, in Ghana. Customary owners in Côte d’Ivoirehave a short time limit within which rights must beregistered to be sustained. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> movement of customarilyheld land out of government land/public land classes isclearest in Uganda, where public land is abolished, andTanzania, where it becomes ‘village land’. More than individualtitle is recognised. Family title is widely provided<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>, especially in Ethiopian law and Malawian policy.Adopti<strong>on</strong> of procedures, limiting transfers of familyland without support of spouses, is provided in Ugandaand Rwanda and proposed in Malawi and Lesotho. Apresumpti<strong>on</strong> of spousal co-ownership exists in Tanzanialand law. Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to secure such a presumpti<strong>on</strong> failed inUganda. Ethiopia and Eritrea recognise male and femaleproperty rights distinctly.Sources: Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001; Alden Wily 2003cto educati<strong>on</strong> and awareness of property rightsam<strong>on</strong>g the comm<strong>on</strong> people, which is discussed ina subsequent secti<strong>on</strong>.Measures to Make Property Systems More GenderEquitable<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> UN Research Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Social Developmentnotes that there has been ‘both c<strong>on</strong>siderableprogress throughout the 1990s in making<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal laws pertaining to land more genderequitable, as well as repeated failures in actuallyputting statutes to work.’ 111 Developing countrieshave, in many cases, enacted laws and policies toprovide women with greater rights to c<strong>on</strong>trol andmanage property. Promising practices combineinstituti<strong>on</strong>al measures, legal prescripti<strong>on</strong>s andsocial policy:Special Units to M<strong>on</strong>itor Gender Issues. Policymakersshould establish special units to c<strong>on</strong>stantlym<strong>on</strong>itor gender issues and follow up <strong>on</strong> en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement.In some envir<strong>on</strong>ments, police services andcourt systems fail to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce women’s propertyrights. When property rights exist de jure but notde facto, policymakers face difficult choices:expend resources to better ensure en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementor work to shift social norms. In countries withlimited capacity the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer route is difficult. Inany country the latter is a major educati<strong>on</strong>al challenge.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>text-specific investigati<strong>on</strong>of how best to shift social norms in ways that91


welcome women holding secure rights to property.This may well be a time-c<strong>on</strong>suming process ofnorms evolving. It is an area in which much additi<strong>on</strong>alresearch is needed.Joint Titling Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts and Comm<strong>on</strong> Property. Governmentsshould register household propertyjointly in the name of both husband and wife. Byvirtue of marriage or sustained free uni<strong>on</strong> (domesticpartnership) real and moveable propertyheld or bought by the male partner should automaticallybe c<strong>on</strong>sidered the co-property of thewoman. Women usually do not have the means toc<strong>on</strong>tribute 50 percent to the purchase of propertyin marriage.Inheritance. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> primary way the poor acquireland is through the family and by inheritance. 112Many <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal systems favour menin distributi<strong>on</strong>s made by inheritance. 113 In somecases, inheritance and successi<strong>on</strong> laws providewidows with <strong>on</strong>ly temporary rights to use spousalproperty after their husbands die. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se rulessubject women to the potential of property grabbing.Many countries have amended c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>sor implemented legislati<strong>on</strong> to guarantee the rightsof women to inherit property <strong>on</strong> an equitable basiswith men. However, in some countries may overridethese provisi<strong>on</strong>s by custom or family law,while a number still maintain discriminatory provisi<strong>on</strong>sin their legal codes. 114 Thus, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women, theexistence of inheritance rules that call <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> maleand female heirs to receive equal c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> intestamentary distributi<strong>on</strong>s are an important step<strong>on</strong> the path towards empowerment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is someevidence that changing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal inheritance lawsmay have the unintended c<strong>on</strong>sequence of promptingmen to specifically disinherit female heirs toavoid passing property to them. 115Educati<strong>on</strong> and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. Women may be unawareof their legally guaranteed property rights.This <strong>on</strong>-the-ground reality suggests that there is ac<strong>on</strong>tinued need to educate women and girls as totheir legal rights to own, use and transfer propertyand to communicate to society broadly the natureof these rights.Intellectual Property Rights and the Rightsof Indigenous Peoples: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Task AheadIn most cases intellectual property is <strong>on</strong>ly indirectlylinked to the ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities of thepoor. However, in the case of indigenous peoplethe issue of intellectual property is often relatedto <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of dispossessi<strong>on</strong> and property misuse.Discussi<strong>on</strong>s have focused <strong>on</strong> a wide range ofissues, including moves to strengthen protecti<strong>on</strong>of traditi<strong>on</strong>al cultural expressi<strong>on</strong>s (TCEs),traditi<strong>on</strong>al knowledge (TK) and genetic resources(GR) against misappropriati<strong>on</strong> and misuse. 116 Inanalogy to this report’s focus <strong>on</strong> indigenous <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msof tenure, rather than indigenous people as such,this secti<strong>on</strong> of the report pays attenti<strong>on</strong> to these<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of intellectual property rights rather than tothe identificati<strong>on</strong> of their bearers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> UN HumanRights Council (Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the Rights of IndigenousPeoples), the C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> BiologicalDiversity 117 , the WTO TRIPS Council, UNCTAD,UNESCO, the FAO and WIPO have paid increasedattenti<strong>on</strong> to the protecti<strong>on</strong> of TCEs, TK, and GR.Some view intellectual property rights as a usefulinstrument <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> of TK, GRand TCEs and as a tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementing a benefit-sharing.Others are more critical and fear atrivialisati<strong>on</strong> of traditi<strong>on</strong>al cultures and possiblemisappropriati<strong>on</strong>. Others still point to a fundamentalc<strong>on</strong>flict between the very noti<strong>on</strong> of intellectualproperty and the cultural values and moralpercepti<strong>on</strong> of many indigenous populati<strong>on</strong>s.While indigenous noti<strong>on</strong>s of collective ownershipand trans-generati<strong>on</strong>al custodianship might becompatible with the overall idea of (intellectual)92


property, some indigenous peoples aim to preventappropriati<strong>on</strong> of natural and cultural resources.In such cases, there is a fundamental c<strong>on</strong>flictbetween indigenous rights and (intellectual) property.In fundamental oppositi<strong>on</strong> to some indigenouscultures, many intellectual property systemsrecognise rights <strong>on</strong> inventi<strong>on</strong>s pertaining to livingmatter. In c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al patent systems, matterknown to the public bel<strong>on</strong>gs to the so-called publicdomain, thus preventing their protecti<strong>on</strong> andallowing their free use by any<strong>on</strong>e. Worse <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> someindigenous people, the c<strong>on</strong>cept of public domainassociated with traditi<strong>on</strong>al intellectual propertylaws has allowed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the appropriati<strong>on</strong> of GR andTK <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the development of inventi<strong>on</strong>s that aresubsequently patented.Intellectual Property Rights in C<strong>on</strong>text. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rightsof indigenous peoples depend <strong>on</strong> and interactwith a wide range of other measures and policies,such as land tenure, envir<strong>on</strong>mental laws andprotecti<strong>on</strong> of endangered species, health, foodand agriculture, water quality, cultural heritageprotecti<strong>on</strong>, access to and exploitati<strong>on</strong> of naturalresources, envir<strong>on</strong>mental management, and soilc<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>. Within this broader horiz<strong>on</strong>, intellectualproperty rights may play a positive role inencouraging creati<strong>on</strong> or protecti<strong>on</strong> of indigenousrights. Such a role includes, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, theprotecti<strong>on</strong> and disclosure of new intellectual creati<strong>on</strong>sthrough the laws of patents and industrialdesigns or avoiding c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong> and decepti<strong>on</strong> andpreventing unfair competiti<strong>on</strong> through the protecti<strong>on</strong>of trademarks and geographical indicati<strong>on</strong>s.Equally relevant are the safeguarding of the integrityof, and rights of attributi<strong>on</strong> to, certain worksand creati<strong>on</strong>s through moral rights’ protecti<strong>on</strong> incopyright, and the protecti<strong>on</strong> of undisclosed in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>from bad faith use or appropriati<strong>on</strong>. Anexample of the use of intellectual property rightsin the protecti<strong>on</strong> of traditi<strong>on</strong>al knowledge relatesto traditi<strong>on</strong>al medicines in the People’s Republicof China, in respect of which several thousandpatents have been granted in past years. 118Way Forward. Notwithstanding useful aspects,many questi<strong>on</strong>s remain as well as importantc<strong>on</strong>cerns:1. C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al intellectual property rights mightnot offer indigenous peoples adequate protecti<strong>on</strong>in situati<strong>on</strong>s where the resource, knowledgeor cultural expressi<strong>on</strong> is already publiclyknown. In this case, the creati<strong>on</strong> of sui generissystems of protecti<strong>on</strong> is needed.2. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> overall purpose of intellectual propertyrights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenous people in both positiveprotecti<strong>on</strong> and negative protecti<strong>on</strong> needs to befurther evaluated.3. Existing and future systems must ensure thatthey do not c<strong>on</strong>tribute to an undue misappropriati<strong>on</strong>of certain intellectual assets of indigenouspeoples.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Dimensi<strong>on</strong>. In additi<strong>on</strong>, because GR/TK and TCEs are often exploited in countries differentfrom the countries of origin, there are callsto establish internati<strong>on</strong>al instruments that take accountof the intangible nature and cross-boundarynature of those comp<strong>on</strong>ents of indigenous life andheritage. This will require examinati<strong>on</strong> of complexissues, such as the questi<strong>on</strong> of ownership/custodianshipof rights, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of protecti<strong>on</strong> to be granted,ways <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ensuring nati<strong>on</strong>als of <strong>on</strong>e country toenjoy rights in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign countries, questi<strong>on</strong> of fairand equitable benefit-sharing in the internati<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>text, recogniti<strong>on</strong> of pers<strong>on</strong>al or moral rights ofindigenous people, ensuring that known resourcesor knowledge already in the public domain cannotbe subject to intellectual property rights, and theneed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> enhanced internati<strong>on</strong>al cooperati<strong>on</strong> inareas such as mutual in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, registrati<strong>on</strong> andmanagement of rights, am<strong>on</strong>g others.93


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Intergovernmental Committee <strong>on</strong> IntellectualProperty and Genetic Resources, Traditi<strong>on</strong>alknowledge and folklore (IGC), established byWIPO Member States in 2000 has adopted an inclusiveapproach. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> IGC has been exploring thepotential of protecting rights of indigenous peoplesthrough c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al intellectual propertyrights and through sui generis systems 119 , workingtowards an understanding of how best to protectTK and TCEs against misappropriati<strong>on</strong>, clarifyingissues such as the positive and negative protecti<strong>on</strong>and working <strong>on</strong> a better understanding of theinternati<strong>on</strong>al dimensi<strong>on</strong> of such protecti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>IGC process has resulted in draft objectives andprinciples <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the legal protecti<strong>on</strong> of TK and TCEsagainst misappropriati<strong>on</strong> and misuse. 120Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming Property Governancein view of the Least AdvantagedCustomer<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> property system is upheld by a system ofgovernance which includes the instituti<strong>on</strong>al orderof the state, procedural rules and relati<strong>on</strong>shipsof interacti<strong>on</strong> between state and stakeholders,ranging from property registrati<strong>on</strong>, spatial planning,z<strong>on</strong>ing, taxing and other aspects of propertymanagement, and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement. Since a propertysystem with general deficits will not produce beneficialresults targeted to the poor, this secti<strong>on</strong>presents broader re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m combined with measuresthat particularly promote the inclusi<strong>on</strong> of the poorin effective property rights protecti<strong>on</strong>. 121Changing Legislati<strong>on</strong>Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the property system to produce tangiblebenefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor might imply the need tochange the law or introduce new legislati<strong>on</strong>. 122Such procedures are time c<strong>on</strong>suming and hard topredict in their final outcome due to political c<strong>on</strong>tingencies.It is thus advisable to first design themost urgent policy measures needed to improvethe property access and security <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor, andthen to assess if the legal basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the measuresis sufficient. If this is the case, it might be moreefficient to seek improvement within a given legalframework. In many cases, however, the implementati<strong>on</strong>of pro-poor property rights, especially<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> customary owners and women, requires legal(statutory or customary) or even c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. 123Agovernment’s large-scale ownership of land,its ability to impose planning restricti<strong>on</strong>sand to expropriate without adequate compensati<strong>on</strong>,c<strong>on</strong>tributes to tenure insecurity and oftendemands legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m as well. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m mightbe undertaken with clear goals of what the newpro-poor property law should look like: allowingprivate individual or group owned property of landunder customary tenure; allowing the franchisingof micro-enterprise with limited liability; allowingthe use of moveable property as collateral; creatinglegal figures of associati<strong>on</strong>al property whichallow the poor to pool and exit property; protectingwomen’s property in and outside the marriageand in inheritance; restricting eminent domain,and introducing protective pro-poor z<strong>on</strong>ing laws,am<strong>on</strong>g others. However, the inclusive procedureof making, implementing, and m<strong>on</strong>itoring thec<strong>on</strong>sequences of the law by further regulati<strong>on</strong>s,as well as securing sustained support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the lawfrom different stakeholders and agents, are asimportant as the c<strong>on</strong>tent of the law itself. Politicalc<strong>on</strong>stellati<strong>on</strong>s might make sweeping andcomprehensive re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms possible and hence advisablein some c<strong>on</strong>texts. If not, it is also possibleto approach the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of property law in a moreprocess-oriented manner. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> following guidingprinciples have been useful in endeavours in differentnati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>texts, where a <strong>on</strong>e-time sweepingre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m was politically impossible:94


• Where c<strong>on</strong>sensus is hard to obtain and/ormedium-term effects hard to anticipate, apragmatic and incremental approach to legalre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is often the best approach.• <strong>Legal</strong> and regulatory re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms can be obtainedwith the support of beneficiaries. But theirshort-term benefits have to be assessed inlight of the provisi<strong>on</strong> of public goods and l<strong>on</strong>gterm effects. 124• <strong>Legal</strong> and regulatory obstacles can be identifiedwith the help of communities. 125• Applying a learning-by-doing approach to legaland regulatory change is beneficial <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theprogress of the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m project. 126In ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to merge legality and legitimacy to solidifyeffective impact and equity of property law,communicati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>sensus-building measureshave proven to be of vital importance. Given thepolitical sensitivity of property issues, securingand maintaining high-level c<strong>on</strong>sensus and commitmentto property re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is critical, especiallyas such support can falter during changes in thepolitical administrati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, ac<strong>on</strong>sensus-building and communicati<strong>on</strong> strategymust be designed and implemented to sustainbroad support.Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Priorities in Land and Real PropertyAdministrati<strong>on</strong>A land and real property administrati<strong>on</strong> systemthat is generally dysfuncti<strong>on</strong>al will not all of asudden produce targeted measures that benefitthe poor. It is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e advisable to make thesystem as a whole more efficient and friendly tothe least advantaged customer. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> combinati<strong>on</strong>of organisati<strong>on</strong>al simplicity and accessibility significantlyimproves the efficiency of registrati<strong>on</strong>and administrati<strong>on</strong>, thereby increasing tenuresecurity of broad sectors of the populati<strong>on</strong> and,as a result, public support. Effectiveness of legalprovisi<strong>on</strong>s depends <strong>on</strong> availability of instituti<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement. In particular, many of the expectedec<strong>on</strong>omic benefits (especially exchangeand use of land as collateral) from secure landrights will not materialise unless a well-functi<strong>on</strong>ing,transparent, and accessible land administrati<strong>on</strong>system is in place. 127Simplicity. Every political entity should <strong>on</strong>ly have<strong>on</strong>e or a strict minimum of well-coordinatedproperty administrati<strong>on</strong> agencies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> integrati<strong>on</strong>of the cadastre, property, intellectual and commercialregistries c<strong>on</strong>tributes to improved outputlegitimacy and investment climate. Experienceworldwide shows that delays and tenure insecurity,due to rivalries and c<strong>on</strong>flicting interests, areinevitable when a number of competing agenciesare simultaneously resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the implementati<strong>on</strong>of property rights. 128Accessibility. Local Presence. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> locati<strong>on</strong>s ofthe agency should be as decentralised as possibleand easily accessible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor who are unableto bear the costs of travelling l<strong>on</strong>g distances inorder to register or transfer property.Reduced Transacti<strong>on</strong> Costs. Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to reduce thenumber of days it takes to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally register propertycan have a positive effect in terms of reducingtransacti<strong>on</strong> costs. So too can reducing the numberof steps buyers and sellers must follow be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maltransfers take place. However, in additi<strong>on</strong> tosuch changes, countries should be encouraged totake additi<strong>on</strong>al steps to reduce transacti<strong>on</strong>s costsin property markets, mainly in organising publicand private legal services in a pro-poor manner. 129A key reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> land sales to be driven into in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality,which can over time threaten the integrityof the registry in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, is the desire to avoidhigh levels of taxati<strong>on</strong>, mainly in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of stampduties, or the need to make in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal payments. In95


additi<strong>on</strong> to setting clear fee structures that are wellpublicized, reducti<strong>on</strong> of stamp duties, possiblyby replacing them with a land tax to be assessedat the local level, would be desirable. Such a tax,complemented by a capital gains tax if necessary,could encourage productive land use and reduceincentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> speculative land accumulati<strong>on</strong>, thusmaking productivity-enhancing outcomes fromland sales markets more likely. Moreover, adjudicati<strong>on</strong>and dispute settlement can be embeddedin a cost-saving, community-based participatoryprocess. It is cost-effective <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the state to investin the capacity of a pool of potential c<strong>on</strong>ciliatorsat a community or district level of government. 130For any first-time registrati<strong>on</strong> of land rights to havea lasting and pro-poor effect, it needs to be integratedwith systems to maintain registry records upto date in a cost-effective way that is in line withwhat users are able and willing to pay.Modern GPS and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> Technology. Inmany c<strong>on</strong>texts of the developing world, the technicalcosts of titling and land registrati<strong>on</strong> havebeen c<strong>on</strong>siderably reduced by computerisati<strong>on</strong>and GPS systems. 131 Modern technology can helpto improve transparency and at the same timemake administrati<strong>on</strong> more accessible. 132 As thepurpose of land registries is to give public noticeof land ownership and transacti<strong>on</strong>s, makingregistry in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> available publicly <strong>on</strong> the Internetand promoting Internet access can reducetransacti<strong>on</strong> cost and by allowing independentcross-checks, greatly increase public c<strong>on</strong>fidencein them. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> transiti<strong>on</strong> to an all-digital, internetenabledland registrati<strong>on</strong> system is not withoutpitfalls. Corrupti<strong>on</strong> can easily increase in theearly phase, because the opportunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> alteringthe records be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e digitisati<strong>on</strong> is high. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> introducti<strong>on</strong>of all-digital and internet-based registrysystems has to be carefully prepared and preemptiveacti<strong>on</strong> to the altering of records taken.Corrupti<strong>on</strong> is reduced dramatically <strong>on</strong>ce the systemsare operati<strong>on</strong>al. 133Financial Self-sustainability. Land administrati<strong>on</strong>instituti<strong>on</strong>s will be viable in the l<strong>on</strong>g term andindependent from political pressure <strong>on</strong>ly if theycan sustain their recurrent operati<strong>on</strong>s financially,without charging more than the poor are able topay. This in turn is a prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all the otherbenefits from land administrati<strong>on</strong> to materialise.Separati<strong>on</strong> of Powers of Land Registrati<strong>on</strong> andPublic Land Management. Land administrati<strong>on</strong>,i.e. all matters relating to land rights should beindependent from the authorities in charge ofstate land management and use. This reduces thepossibility of abusive practices where the state is<strong>on</strong>ly the means through which individuals pursuetheir particular interests and of which the poorare usually the first victims.Increasing Transparency in Public Land Use andPlanningGovernments’ large-scale ownership of land,its ability to impose planning restricti<strong>on</strong>sand to expropriate without adequate compensati<strong>on</strong>also c<strong>on</strong>tributes to tenure insecurity of thepoor who have no government lobby. 134Define Government’s Land Rights and Duties andEstablish an Inventory of Government Land: Invirtually all countries, the government nominallyowns large amounts of land. However, the extentof such claims and associated rights and obligati<strong>on</strong>sare often not well defined. At worst, thisencourages sell-offs of public assets to the wellc<strong>on</strong>nectedleading to a speculative accumulati<strong>on</strong>of large n<strong>on</strong>-productive land holdings or c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s.Keeping public land at the necessary minimumand defining the resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities of differentlevels of government in terms of managing publicland would be a first step that should be followedby a inventorying and registering of state land96


and the establishment of transparent administrativeprocesses at all levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> granting, selling,and leasing of state lands.Strictly Circumscribe C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Expropriati<strong>on</strong>of Land: As transferring land from agricultureto n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural or urban uses is a corollaryof ec<strong>on</strong>omic development, an important issuethat undermines tenure security in much of thedeveloping world — and which has often causedgreat hardship to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer land owners — is thegovernment’s far-reaching ability to expropriateland with real compensati<strong>on</strong> often far below marketrates. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> threat of expropriati<strong>on</strong> has servedto undermine tenure security and investment andhas also led to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sales in anticipati<strong>on</strong> ofexpropriati<strong>on</strong> that often invited corrupti<strong>on</strong> andshady property deals involving state agencies.Productivity was impaired as the state apparatushad often neither the means nor the incentivesto invest in or effectively use the land acquired,thereby often leaving the potentially most valuableland undeveloped. One reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this is that,in many countries, even land <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> private uses willfirst have to be acquired by the state, somethingthat can greatly increase the transacti<strong>on</strong> costfaced by private investors. Eliminating such rules,c<strong>on</strong>straining expropriati<strong>on</strong> to cases where a narrowlydefined public purpose is at stake, whileallowing land owners or users to negotiate directlywith interested parties in the remainder of thecases (with the possibility to draw <strong>on</strong> mediati<strong>on</strong> ifneeded) can eliminate a key source of uncertaintyand corrupti<strong>on</strong>.Z<strong>on</strong>ing and City PlanningZ<strong>on</strong>ing and planning is <strong>on</strong>e of the main causes ofexclusi<strong>on</strong> of the poor from legal and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal cityand peri-urban development processes. On theother hand, the right use of z<strong>on</strong>ing and spatialplanning can become a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>midable instrument oflegal empowerment. 135 Although this is perhapsmost comm<strong>on</strong>ly a feature of the rural-urban z<strong>on</strong>eof transiti<strong>on</strong>, it is also a feature within urban areas,and within rural areas. 136 Especially changesin use from agriculture to urban residential orcommercial purposes usually multiply the valueof land significantly, and c<strong>on</strong>sequently augmentthe potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> abuse. Peri-urban areas needto be better planned if they are to be more effectivein promoting sustainable pro-poor urbandevelopment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ambit of interventi<strong>on</strong>s hasto expand bey<strong>on</strong>d slum upgrading and tenureregularisati<strong>on</strong> to defining the urban developmentframework within which access to land and landdevelopment rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor becomes possible.137 Spatial and urban planning can be a majordriving <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce behind higher living standards andwealth generati<strong>on</strong>. 138 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> relevance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> urbanplanning is heightened in the idea that resp<strong>on</strong>sibility,incentives and ownership should be alignedto maximise desired ends. 139Eliminate Inappropriate Planning Regulati<strong>on</strong>s.Overcoming extra-legality in urban areas will beimpossible without a careful review of planningregulati<strong>on</strong>s - some of which, such as minimumlot sizes, were designed with the explicit purposeof segregating property markets. While regulati<strong>on</strong>smay be introduced with more benevolentgoals, they may n<strong>on</strong>etheless affect the poor negativelyand, through their impacts <strong>on</strong> urban <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms,be envir<strong>on</strong>mentally and socially harmful. Whileit will be dangerous to generalise, in practice the<strong>on</strong>ly reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>tinued existence of harmfulregulati<strong>on</strong>s is either limited knowledge <strong>on</strong>alternatives or the fact that they benefit powerfulvested interest groups who are generally not thepoor.Establish Transparent and Participatory Land UsePlanning: Even if rules are well justified, in manycountries, land use planning follows n<strong>on</strong>-transparentand highly centralised processes. This97


implies that rules often have little relevance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the reality of the poor. Focusing central ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts <strong>on</strong>defining clear per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance criteria <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> land useand ways of en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement while leaving detailedplanning to the local level are likely to result inplans that focus <strong>on</strong> relevant issues, have higherlocal acceptance, and thus stand a better chanceof actually being implemented.Avoiding Ghetto-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> by Mixed Neighbourhoods.New and ‘good old urbanism’ definesalternatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> urban growth and communitiesbased <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cepts of mixed neighbourhoods,mixed land use, diversity and public identity.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se c<strong>on</strong>cepts work towards integrating urbanismand envir<strong>on</strong>mentalism, and joining ratherthan segregating the poor and ethnic minoritiesin diverse communities. 140Special Social Interest Z<strong>on</strong>es. Forming mixedneighbourhoods does not substitute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> additi<strong>on</strong>alz<strong>on</strong>ing and planning measures that canwork to improve existing slums. Here, specialinterest z<strong>on</strong>es can create protective and empoweringenvir<strong>on</strong>ments of residence and businessactivity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the urban and peri-urban poor.In Brazil several planning measures have beentaken to provide secure c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of livingand livelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. For instance, urbanz<strong>on</strong>es which have favelas, corticos (collectivehousing, popular subdivisi<strong>on</strong>s), and other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msof housing and home-based ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities<strong>on</strong> vacant lands, can be declared as ZEIS orSpecial Social Interest Z<strong>on</strong>es under municipallaw. Special rules are drafted and simplifiedprocedures adopted <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> each ZEIS by a localcommittee <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> regularisati<strong>on</strong> of land occupati<strong>on</strong>and use of land by the poor. ZEIS havenow been adopted relatively successfully by anumber of Brazilian cities. 141C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Private Developers. One importantprovisi<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance of the progressiveUrban Development and Housing Act of 1992 ofthe Philippines 142 , is Balanced Housing Developmentwhereby developers of proposed subdivisi<strong>on</strong>sare required to develop 20 percent of theland <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> housing low income communities. Asimilar provisi<strong>on</strong> of the Government of the Indianstate of Madhya Pradesh enacted as part of theCol<strong>on</strong>isers’ Act requires 15 percent of the land tobe reserved <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> without shelter households or paymentof a sum equivalent to the officially determinedprice of the land to be reserved. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> policyhas made land available <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> housing more than6,000 poor households in central city locati<strong>on</strong>s inthe city of Bhopal al<strong>on</strong>e and substantial funds <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>land procurement and development. 143Density Mixed Use Z<strong>on</strong>es legitimise densely built,small plots and home based businesses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>draft Nati<strong>on</strong> Slum Policy of India 144 proposes tointegrate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements into city planningby designating them as high-density mixed usez<strong>on</strong>es, to legitimise densely built, small plotsand home-based businesses. It also proposesthat <strong>on</strong>ly slums in envir<strong>on</strong>mental risk areas andland use z<strong>on</strong>es <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> essential services and facilitiesshould be relocated. All others should beregularised and their land use z<strong>on</strong>ing should bechanged to high-density mixed-use. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nati<strong>on</strong>alHousing and Habitat Policy propose that landshould be z<strong>on</strong>ed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> housing the poor in city masterplans. 145Reversing the Development Sequence in SlumUpgrading. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> strategy of reversing the developmentsequence by first allotting secured plotswith <strong>on</strong>ly bare minimum services, with provisi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> incremental improvement gives the poor sustainableownership and participati<strong>on</strong> in the valueincrease of property. Such measures match theaf<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dability of allottees and assure that even thepoorest get access to secure land and housing,98


which develop into a fully serviced neighbourhoodin the l<strong>on</strong>ger term. 146Supporting Street Entrepreneurs. Many Indianstates have adopted the Central Government’sNati<strong>on</strong>al Street Vendors’ Policy of 2004, aimedat recognising and planning <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbut widespread activity of hawking and vendingin cities and to provide basic facilities such asspace, water and sanitati<strong>on</strong> and access to credit.147 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy itself was framed after more thana decade of lobbying by NGOs and street vendorsfederati<strong>on</strong>s. Under the policy local governmentsof cities such as Bhopal, Hyderabad, Kolkata andDelhi have delineated Hawkers’ Z<strong>on</strong>es. Initialindicati<strong>on</strong>s are that this has ended harassment ofthe poor and provided them with security to carryout income earning activities. 148Involving Stakeholders in Spatial Planning. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>strategy of using a survey to make claims anddraw attenti<strong>on</strong> of the authorities to poor livingc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s was first used in Mumbai in 1987 bypavement dwellers supported by <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Society <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Promoti<strong>on</strong> of Area Resource Centres (SPARC).This was followed by women pavement dwellersidentifying potential vacant lands in the city<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their relocati<strong>on</strong>, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing the city governmentto act. This strategy paved the way <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> civicauthorities to recognise the role of civil societyorganisati<strong>on</strong>s in developing resp<strong>on</strong>sive housingsoluti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor, and later participating inframing the relocati<strong>on</strong> and rehabilitati<strong>on</strong> policy<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the World Bank funded Mumbai Urban TransportProject. Similar initiatives are taking placein Thailand with the support of CODI (CommunityOrganisati<strong>on</strong>s Development Institute), which is agovernment organisati<strong>on</strong> created to facilitate localhousing improvement and livelihood initiatives ofcommunity groups. 149Implementati<strong>on</strong> and Dispute SettlementExpand Opti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>flict Resoluti<strong>on</strong>. Implementati<strong>on</strong>is a decisive element of propertyrights governance. Where it fails, it can nullifyor c<strong>on</strong>siderably reduce the effectiveness of allother elements. Developing countries are oftenat loss of stable and predictable implementati<strong>on</strong>and dispute settlement instituti<strong>on</strong>s. Traditi<strong>on</strong>alinstituti<strong>on</strong>s can resolve some <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of localiseddisputes. But they are not well equipped to addressdisputes that cut across groups from differentcommunities (e.g. nomads and sedentaryagriculturalists), across ethnic boundaries, or thatare between individuals and the state. Even so,expanding the range of opti<strong>on</strong>s to resolve landc<strong>on</strong>flicts systematically and out of court can havelarge benefits, especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>women who otherwise are often unable to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cetheir legal rights. 150 In many c<strong>on</strong>texts, Third PartyArbitrati<strong>on</strong> Courts (TPACs) can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered anec<strong>on</strong>omic and social success. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se mechanismsoffer effective protecti<strong>on</strong> of property rights and/oreffective resoluti<strong>on</strong>s of disputes over c<strong>on</strong>testedproperty arrangements, especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> disenfranchisedwomen.Alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> is very promisingbut has its pitfalls. In general, successof alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> depends <strong>on</strong>certain standards and practices. An importantc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> is the right of poor people to appointjudges of their choice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>. Butit is equally imperative that the alternative disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanism be linked to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement and not operate totally outside therealm of the legal system. Rules have to be craftedin accordance with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsocial c<strong>on</strong>text. If supported by aid, financialsustainability should be guaranteed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the timeafter d<strong>on</strong>or support has stopped. 15199Include Property Issues in Post-c<strong>on</strong>flict Settle-


ments and Natural Disaster Management. In themany situati<strong>on</strong>s where land issues have oftenbeen at the root of broader civil strife, failure todevote proper attenti<strong>on</strong> to these issues, includingways of managing land access by returnees, caneasily undermine their sustainability of such settlementsand sow the seeds <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> violence. Learningfrom successful examples to address land-relatedgrievances and settle large numbers of people ina rapid and decentralised way together with waysthat will prevent limited c<strong>on</strong>flicts from festeringand escalating into larger <strong>on</strong>es can help to avoidmuch broader clashes, often with very damaginghumanitarian and ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>sequences. 152Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the Property System asa Market of Assets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the PoorA functi<strong>on</strong>al property system allows <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>of assets into fungible property rightsand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the exchange of those rights in open markets.In order to benefit the poor, real propertyand credit markets need to be developed andthey need to be regulated where they systematicallywork against the poor. In general, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msshould aim at opening the door to the poor to abroadened asset base. Guaranteeing the poor theright to property and to leverage property in themarket is a multi-stakeholder task best achievedby close partnerships between the state, the privatesector and civil society.Market DevelopmentA Pro-poor Framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Land Sale Markets.Historically, most land sales were due to distressthat required defaulting landowners to cede c<strong>on</strong>trolof their land to m<strong>on</strong>eylenders, who amassedhuge amounts of lands. 153 However, data <strong>on</strong>land sales over 20 years in India illustrate theimportance of land sales markets and of beingin the land markets: First, they transferred landto better cultivators and from land-abundant toland-scarce households, allowing the land-scarceto improve their welfare 154 without making sellersworse off. Sales markets were indeed thinner,more affected by life-cycle events, and lessredistributive than those <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rentals. Land salesmarkets helped purchasers, many of whom were<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merly landless, to accumulate n<strong>on</strong>-land assetsand significantly enhance their welfare. 155 Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tsat redistributive land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m will need to aim atcomplementing what market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces are achieving.Market development with the poor in mind oughtto be pursued by:• Granting freedom of c<strong>on</strong>tract, definiti<strong>on</strong> ofobligati<strong>on</strong>s, remedies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> failing to fulfil obligati<strong>on</strong>sand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> terminating obligati<strong>on</strong>s orderly,guidance <strong>on</strong> how to c<strong>on</strong>clude a c<strong>on</strong>tract, definiti<strong>on</strong>of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of c<strong>on</strong>tract (oral or written);identificati<strong>on</strong> of invalid transacti<strong>on</strong>s.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> land purchase and sale easier <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepoor by minimising c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s such as <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maleducati<strong>on</strong> or experience in agriculture. Providemodel sales c<strong>on</strong>tracts the poor can rely <strong>on</strong>.• Keeping leasing rules simple and clear.• Reducing transacti<strong>on</strong> costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor byavoiding overly precise mapping, avoiding repetiti<strong>on</strong>of platting parcels, not covering initialplatting fees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor.• Avoiding notary fees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> small transacti<strong>on</strong>s;keeping registrati<strong>on</strong> fees and transacti<strong>on</strong> taxesvery low <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> small transacti<strong>on</strong>s and exemptingnew and small land owners from registrati<strong>on</strong>fees and tax; putting to severe need testand cost-benefit analysis every administrativeinterventi<strong>on</strong> into land deals and eliminatinginterventi<strong>on</strong>s which do not stand the test.• Granting preferential rights to buy to co-owners,neighbours, or leaseholders of land.100


Box 5 Sale of land: examples oflegal issuesIn the collective certificate of land ownership award(CLOA) system of the Philippines not even a majorityof the collective can decide to sell, mortgage or usethe title as collateral to obtain <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal credit. Underthe Comprehensive Agrarian Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Program of thesame country, there was a prohibiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> any <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mof transfer within 10 years of award. In additi<strong>on</strong>, afive-hectare ceiling <strong>on</strong> ownership was set and <strong>on</strong>lyqualified farmers can buy awarded land. This didnot stop but increase transfers and pushed theminto extra-legality with adverse c<strong>on</strong>sequences <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor (NCLEP Philippines 2006). In Armenia,a three-year moratorium was imposed after landprivatisati<strong>on</strong> in 1991. In Ukraine, a 6-year salesmoratorium will expire in 2005, but many exempti<strong>on</strong>shave circumvented this measure. A Kyrgyzmoratorium <strong>on</strong> the sale of agricultural land was putinto place when land was privatised and allocated,but it was subsequently lifted in September 2001.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Moldovan Land Code c<strong>on</strong>tained a 10-year moratorium<strong>on</strong> sales that was declared unc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>aland lifted in late 1996. Some countries have attemptedto protect new landowners from the dangerof mortgage <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eclosure by setting moratoria <strong>on</strong>mortgages; <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, a 1997 Russian law prohibitedmortgages <strong>on</strong> agricultural land (Russian <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>On Mortgage 1997).Ceilings of ownership work in some c<strong>on</strong>texts <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>some time but have adverse c<strong>on</strong>sequences <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor in the l<strong>on</strong>g run. 156 Sales moratoria arec<strong>on</strong>sidered a successful practice, provided thetime is used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public educati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> land values,financial literacy, and participati<strong>on</strong> in land markets.157 Where the moratoria extend over a l<strong>on</strong>geramount of time, they install barriers which do notcorresp<strong>on</strong>d to the needs and capabilities of thepoor. Notwithstanding prohibiti<strong>on</strong>s, land pawningtransacti<strong>on</strong>s, direct sales, sales through waiver ofrights, sales through pawning, and sales throughland c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> arrangements are sometimeswidespread. Ultimately, these transfers augmentthe risk of losing land rights.Bringing the Poor into the Market: Opportunitiesand Resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities of Medium and Large Companies.Large companies, regardless of their industry,can stimulate local markets and increase the valueof the real, moveable, and equity property of thepoor by enabling them to become active participantsin their chains of value additi<strong>on</strong>. Inclusi<strong>on</strong>of the poor in the value chain creates businessopportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the next decade. Designing businessmodels to address this challenge opens newopportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> company growth as well as <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>broadening the assets base <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. Manybusiness leaders now believe that the planet’s poormust become part of company growth strategy,and that the presence of their enterprise in a developingnati<strong>on</strong> will be crucial to their l<strong>on</strong>g-termsuccess, with the advantage going to early movers.To be successful, however, such projects must bebased <strong>on</strong> the real needs, capabilities, and realitiesof low-income communities. 158<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> focus <strong>on</strong> business implies focus <strong>on</strong> profitability.If the projects realise the goal of profitability,this means that they have no limited, fixed budget.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> new business can thus become replicable andlead to a remarkable empowering impact. Providingbusiness soluti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor and with thepoor can cover a multitude of activities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> guidingprinciple is that companies should engage thepoor in a business relati<strong>on</strong>ship that relates directlyto their core commercial operati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor may be customers and can profit frommore af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable products. 159 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor may also bebusiness partners, suppliers, and/or distributors.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered as partners creatingadded value at every stage of the delivery of aservice/product designed to serve their needs. 160By bringing small entrepreneurs and local small101


and medium enterprises (SMEs) into their valuechains, established internati<strong>on</strong>al business canempower the poor and accelerate skill transfer. 161Companies addressing basic needs, such as utilitiesand health care providers, can c<strong>on</strong>tribute significantlyto local development by expanding theirservices to more low-income communities. 162Extractive companies often find themselves doingbusiness with low income governments andcommunities through their drilling and miningc<strong>on</strong>tracts, licences, fees and royalties. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y thushave a major influence <strong>on</strong> the paths of developmentof poor countries. 163Moveable and Intangible Property: A MissingPiece of the Development PuzzleAlthough many of the citizens of the developingworld lack secure rights to use and transfer realproperty, most of them actually do own some tangible(moveable) or intangible property (businessskills and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>al schemes). 164 Peasantsand urban street entrepreneurs alike use moveableproperty as means of producti<strong>on</strong>. To the extentthat this type of property is held securely and canbe used to access credit to create and grow businesses,the poor will have increased opportunities.Collateralising moveable and intangible propertycan play an important role in a nati<strong>on</strong>’s developmentstrategy. 165 In many parts of the developedworld, a broad array of pers<strong>on</strong>al property, bothtangible and intangible, can be used legally ascollateral to secure a loan, whereas in many partsof the developing world, <strong>on</strong>ly a small fracti<strong>on</strong> ofthis property can be used as collateral. 166 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reis evidence that expanding the number of itemsthat can be used legally as collateral reduces thecost of credit. And because more people can borrowif more types of property can be used as collateralcredit markets become more competitive.Lenders pass al<strong>on</strong>g their savings to customers,by reducing fees and offering lower interest ratesand competitive <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces also help to keep the priceof credit lower than it otherwise would be. 167For small-scale enterprises, such cost savings canhave a major positive impact. SME entrepreneursof developing countries routinely list financingand access to credit as their major obstacle togrowth. 168 To the extent that collateral law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mmakes borrowing easier and less costly, it couldvery well serve to promote SME development inmany countries.Creating a public moveable and intangible propertyregistry (or, more simply, a registry listingstolen items), and enacting legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms thatmake it easier to use moveable and intangibleproperty as collateral, will expand access to credit<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. Experience in a variety of developingcountries (<strong>on</strong>e should include here Georgia,Madagascar, Colombia, Albania, and Bosnia,am<strong>on</strong>g others) suggests that there are at leastthree important legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that would serve toallow the poor to leverage movable and intangibleproperty. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are:• Allowing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom of c<strong>on</strong>tract in loan agreementsso that borrowers are free to use moveableand intangible property as collateral.Lenders and borrowers should be free to determine,between themselves, which property willbe used as collateral <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a loan.• Provide secured creditors with first prioritywith pledged collateral. Evidence that a creditoris secured may be obtained from a collateralregistry.• Creditors should be empowered to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce collateralagreements quickly by means of summaryproceedings.If developing nati<strong>on</strong>s allowed borrowers greaterfreedom to use moveable and intangible property102


as collateral more of the poor would be able tocreate credit histories. For borrowers, the greatestrisk is losing real property. With moveableproperty, the loss is proporti<strong>on</strong>ate and collateralcan be better matched to the size of the loan. 169<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor may be understandably hesitant to usethe title to their home as collateral <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a loan, butif they can use a refrigerator as collateral, theymay be able to borrow smaller sums that will helpthem start or build a business or send a child toschool.Creating a moveable and intangible registry isless expensive than the creati<strong>on</strong> of land registries— it may take as little as $500,000 and no morethan two years of time to create a self-financingmoveable and intangible property registry. 170 Fordeveloping countries, amending laws and regulati<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> collateral, in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with the establishmentof registry may be a feasible, cost-effectiveand pro-poor development strategy.When c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of instability and c<strong>on</strong>flict exist,when the rule of law is absent, and when otherinstituti<strong>on</strong>al structures do not appear to be functi<strong>on</strong>ing,<strong>on</strong>e should expect that re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m aimed atimproving the security and usefulness of moveableand intangible property would not, by itself,create ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth.Equity Based Asset-Building <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the PoorCreating Property Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor by ShareholderSystemsInnovative <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of n<strong>on</strong>-real estate can extendthe asset base of the poor and n<strong>on</strong>-credit basedshareholder ownership, enabled by the fungiblenature of property rights. Unlike land and housing,the reproductive potential of n<strong>on</strong>-tangibleobjects of property is potentially unlimited. Whilethe private sector is at the heart of this enterprise,the state has an important role to play inguaranteeing c<strong>on</strong>tracts and transacti<strong>on</strong>s and increating an overarching enabling framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>equity based pro-poor business and banking practices.Natural Resources Requiring Capital IntensiveExtracti<strong>on</strong>, Treatment and Distributi<strong>on</strong>. In the caseof state co-ownership of fossil energy reserves, thelocal populati<strong>on</strong>s should be included in the chainof value additi<strong>on</strong> by tradable shares in generalpublic funds. Many of the poor people of the worldlive in lands rich in natural resources that are c<strong>on</strong>trolledthrough government ownership. Distributingshares to populati<strong>on</strong>s or other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of ownershipparticipati<strong>on</strong> in state owned companies exploitingnatural resources will provide the poor with capitalthat can, am<strong>on</strong>g other things, propel the expansi<strong>on</strong>of small businesses. An alternative opti<strong>on</strong> is distributingtitles to special funds created by governmentsto invest profits yielded by commodities.Recent experience in Kenya is illustrative of howthe poor are willing to c<strong>on</strong>vert their rights intocapital, given the right framework. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> offeringof Ken Gen State Owned Corporati<strong>on</strong> intendedto raise 8 billi<strong>on</strong> Kenyan Schillings, but insteadraised 26 billi<strong>on</strong> Schillings and drew three timesthe number of anticipated investors, many ofwho immediately tripled their m<strong>on</strong>ey. As a resultinvestments in the stock market have grownsince 2002 from 50,000 investors to more than750,000 with much of the growth coming fromrural areas. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> exchange’s total value jumpedfrom 1 billi<strong>on</strong> Schillings to 12 billi<strong>on</strong> Schillings,an amount that is predicted to grow following thebiggest initial public offering in Kenyan historyof cell ph<strong>on</strong>e giant Safaricom. Natural resourcesrich countries such as Iraq, Venezuela, Chile,Peru, C<strong>on</strong>go and South Africa could easily empowertheir poor people by directly transferringproperty of their oil or minerals. 175103


Box 6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Grameen BankStill the 7.06 milli<strong>on</strong> poor borrowers of the bank, ofwhich 97 per cent are women, own the most illustriousexample of a broadening of the asset base of the poorby shareholder strategies. Borrowers of Grameen Bankat present own 94 per cent of the total equity of thebank. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government owns the remaining 6 percent.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Grameen Bank is impressive in size and impact.It has 2,399 branches. It works in 76,848 villages.Total staff is 22,169. 171 Loan recovery rate is 98.28per cent. 172 Grameen Bank finances 100 per cent of itsoutstanding loan from deposits of which over 60 percent come from the bank’s own borrowers. Many borrowersare moving ahead in businesses faster thanothers. Grameen Bank provides larger loans, calledmicro-enterprise loans, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> these fast moving members.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no restricti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the loan size. So far 1,085,959members took micro-enterprise loans. A total of Tk23.42 billi<strong>on</strong> (US$364.91 milli<strong>on</strong>) has been disbursedunder this category of loans. Average loan size is Tk21,566 (US$313), maximum loan taken so far is Tk 1.2milli<strong>on</strong> (US$19,897).Scholarships: Scholarships are given to the high per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mingchildren of Grameen borrowers, with priority <strong>on</strong>girl children. Up to March 2007, scholarships amountingto US$550,000 have been awarded to 48,974children. During 2007, US$775,000 will be awardedto about 30,000 children, at various levels of educati<strong>on</strong>.By March 2007, 15,754 students received highereducati<strong>on</strong> loans, of them 14,739 at various universities;176 are studying in medical schools, 335 are studyingto become engineers, and 504 are studying in otherprofessi<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>s.Grameen Bank-Created Companies: A number ofcompanies were created by Grameen Bank, asseparate legal entities, to spin off some projectswithin Grameen Bank funded by d<strong>on</strong>ors. D<strong>on</strong>or fundstransferred to Grameen Fund were given as a loan fromGrameen Bank. 173 Grameen Bank created an internalfund called Social Advancement Fund (SAF) by imputinginterest <strong>on</strong> all the grant m<strong>on</strong>ey it received fromvarious d<strong>on</strong>ors. SAF has been c<strong>on</strong>verted into a separatecompany to carry out its mandate to undertake socialadvance activities am<strong>on</strong>g the Grameen borrowers, suchas, educati<strong>on</strong>, health, technology, etc. 174Banking <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor. As often menti<strong>on</strong>ed, thepoor still make relatively little use of titles ascommercial credit. This is due to the perceivedrisks involved, as well as the difficulty or impossibilityof accessing credit. One ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t to begin toaddress the problem associated with low levelsof banking activity am<strong>on</strong>g low-income earnersare Mzansi accounts, low-fee bank accounts designed<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> people working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se accounts are offered by a group of SouthAfrican commercial banks in c<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with theSouth African Post Office, and they have beenquite successful. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y allow people to become‘banked’, providing a means to establish a credithistory while risking less than the title to realproperty.Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the Property System as anInstrument of Social PolicyProperty re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m with the poor in mind can be anefficient instrument of social policy with benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>society at large. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> state can foster the social fabricthrough property rights, such as in housing andneighbourhood development, low interest loans andthe low priced sale of state land tied to c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sof productivity and market based redistributi<strong>on</strong> ofprivate land. Local political authorities can also seethe re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m path towards more equitable propertyregimes as an opportunity to install participatoryprocesses and broader social dialogue in order topromote self-resp<strong>on</strong>sibility and social cohesi<strong>on</strong> viaownership not <strong>on</strong>ly of property but also of the policyprocesses that establish property rules.104


Enhancing Access to Land and Real PropertyLandlessness is <strong>on</strong>e of the greatest predictorsof poverty. Increasing security of propertyrights will have limited direct benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thosewho do not have any real assets at all. Whileland rental markets can, in rural areas, providean important avenue <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> greater land access bythe poor and landless, they need to be complementedby other measures to increase the assetendowment of the poor in situati<strong>on</strong>s where hugeinequalities persist.Create an Enabling Envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rental Markets.In most developing countries land and realproperty rental markets are underdeveloped. Butland and real property rentals are increasing. Productivity-enhancingrental transacti<strong>on</strong>s will notfully materialise or the poor may be excluded, ifleasehold tenure is insecure or restricti<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>strainland leasing. 176 Replacing them with policiesthat facilitate renting will improve access to land bythose remaining in the rural sector. 177 More robustand transparent guarantees should strengthen thepositi<strong>on</strong> of slum dwellers in rental arrangementsand protect them from arbitrary evicti<strong>on</strong>.<strong>Legal</strong> Recogniti<strong>on</strong> of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Settlements.Ensure the property rights of urban shantydwellersand rural state land squatters by grantingthem title to their already occupied landsor suitable alternatives (see Secti<strong>on</strong> 5 of thisChapter), and introduce anti-evicti<strong>on</strong> rights, limitati<strong>on</strong>sof compulsory acquisiti<strong>on</strong>s, resettlementpolicies, adverse possessi<strong>on</strong> rights and family/group rights. 178<str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> Land Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Effective <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> IncreasingProductive Assets by the Poor. Land markets,or <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of existing land rights, are nota panacea <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> addressing structural inequalitieswhich reduce productivity of land use and holdback development. 179 To overcome the legacy ofBox 7 Mexico: the poor rely <strong>on</strong>pawnshops instead ofbanksMost Mexican citizens do not have access to bankingand <strong>on</strong>ly 13 percent hold mortgage debt. In theabsence of financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s, the poor and lowermiddle classes rely <strong>on</strong> pawn shops. As movablecollateral valuati<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>sumer goods is difficult toestablish, the value of the collateral typically shortchangesthe c<strong>on</strong>sumer. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> annualised rate chargedby these pawnshops ranges from 48 percentcharged by a n<strong>on</strong>-profit pawnshop to 160 percent bya <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>-profit pawnshop. Some pawnshops will accepthouses as collateral (whether the underlying landis legally owned or not) in exchange <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> three yearloans.(La Crónica de Hoy, El top ten de la usura: la casade empeño Mister M<strong>on</strong>ey cobra 159.6 percent deinterés anual; Prenda Fácil, 146 percent; M<strong>on</strong>tepío48 percent. Mexico City, October 9, 2006.)such inequality, ways of redistributing assets suchas land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m will be needed. While the post-warexperiences of China, Japan, Korea and Taiwanshow that land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m can improve equity andec<strong>on</strong>omic per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance, many other cases whereland re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m could not be fully implemented oreven had negative c<strong>on</strong>sequences illustrate the difficultiesinvolved. Where redistributive land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mis found to be more cost-effective in overcomingstructural inequalities than alternatives, it needs tobe complemented by access to managerial ability,technology, credit, and markets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the new ownersto become competitive. A possible alternative, theimpact of which needs to be explored more systematically,is the distributi<strong>on</strong> of small house andgarden plots to the destitute to increase their foodsecurity and social status while at the same timeallowing them to climb at least the first rung <strong>on</strong>the property rights ladder.Community-Based Land Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. As an alterna-105


tive to authoritative reallocati<strong>on</strong> of land, community-basedland re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m projects provide fundsto groups of beneficiaries to purchase land. Whilebeing market-based, the idea behind such measuresis that land sale markets often do not moveland to those who have n<strong>on</strong>e or to small efficientproducers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> provisi<strong>on</strong> of funds is made availableunder the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> of a productive purposeand when land markets are sufficiently developed.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> procedure is legally less complicatedand politically less sensitive than in compulsoryacquisiti<strong>on</strong> programmes. <strong>Legal</strong> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m might berequired in the determinati<strong>on</strong> of legal pers<strong>on</strong>alityof associati<strong>on</strong>s or incorporati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the groupseligible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> funding, but it is probably best to letbeneficiaries experiment with a number of possibleassociati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. <strong>Legal</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality regardingthe groups of beneficiaries does, however,leave room <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the pursuit of other social purposes.In Andhra Pradesh, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance, purchasedland is given in the name of women <strong>on</strong>ly. 180Limit Administrative C<strong>on</strong>trols <strong>on</strong> Sales. Oftenthere is little justificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy measures torestrict land sales which drive land sales undergroundand undermine access to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal credit.If there is an issue of asymmetries in power, accessto insurance, and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> leading toundesirable land market outcomes or speculativeland accumulati<strong>on</strong>, safety nets and other measures,including ways of redistributing land, willbe more appropriate to prevent distress sales.Moreover, land taxes with temporal and user-orientedc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality can curb speculative demandand encourage better land use, while providingrevenue <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> local governments. 181Make benefits from past land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m permanent:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are also many situati<strong>on</strong>s where those whohave received land rights in the past are unableto enjoy the full benefits because they have notreceived full ownership rights or because transferabilityof their rights was restricted. As sec<strong>on</strong>dgenerati<strong>on</strong> problems can threaten to undermineearlier successes, it will be important to providefull ownership rights to those affected, if needbe by identifying innovative approaches — e.g.,a credit-financed purchase of residual ownershiprights by <strong>on</strong>e of the parties involved.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Benefi cial Effects of Property RelatedEducati<strong>on</strong> and Relevant In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.Households’ awareness and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> ofrights has a significant and large impact<strong>on</strong> the positive outcomes of property regimes. 182<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is evidence of a str<strong>on</strong>g and positive relati<strong>on</strong>shipbetween households’ objective knowledgeof the law and land-related investmentsand, through such investments, <strong>on</strong> productivityand land values. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fact that often <strong>on</strong>ly a minorityof land users is aware of relevant legal provisi<strong>on</strong>simplies that the li<strong>on</strong>’s share of the associatedproductivity gains remains to be realised.Given their low cost, especially if compared toef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to demarcate lands, programmes to disseminatethe law and make households awareof their rights could thus have very high returnsand should accompany any property rights re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mpolicy. Scientific evidence as well as grass-rootsc<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor dem<strong>on</strong>strates that socialpolicy should promote legal literacy and proceduralassistance to close the discrepancy betweenlegal provisi<strong>on</strong>s and ground realities, and to helpthose who are given rights through the law to exercisethem. 183Promoting Access to HousingUrban Infrastructure projects, housing and propertyrights creati<strong>on</strong> can be pursued together andare mutually rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing. 184 As a sector, housingis a local ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity, generating income,106


Box 8 Example of Singapore:public housing asec<strong>on</strong>omic stimulantSingapore’s experience has shown that public housingc<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> expenditure can have a multipliereffect that stimulates the ec<strong>on</strong>omy and c<strong>on</strong>tributesemployment growth in the building and c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>industry. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ratio of c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> to the country’sGDP has increased both absolutely and relativelyover the past three decades, about 40 percent ofGDP. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> industry has a labour absorpti<strong>on</strong>capacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> skilled and unskilled workers.Estimates indicate that the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>on</strong>eunit of public housing at the time of the Housingand Development Board’s (HDB) first building programme(1960-65) would generate employment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>a pers<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> nine m<strong>on</strong>ths directly at the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>site, while a HDB building programme of 10,000units per year would create 15,000 jobs. In additi<strong>on</strong>with the policy of reserving about 10 percent of newtown land <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> industrial development public housinginvestment has generated a significant numberof new jobs near the homes of new town residents,especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women who otherwise might not haveentered the labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce. Over the 10-year period1970-80 female participati<strong>on</strong> rates increased from29.5 percent to 44.3 percent. Thus, housing shouldnot be viewed simply as a means of resolving shelterproblems but also as a potentially leading sector ofgrowth in nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Source: Yuen 2002.employing local labour, and re-circulating incomeinto the local ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Housing producti<strong>on</strong> producesspill over effects such as the developmentof skilled labour, and producti<strong>on</strong> of householdgoods. 185 Further, from a macroec<strong>on</strong>omic perspective,the housing sector has a broad impact<strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance affecting prices, investmentand employment, strengthening thefinancial sector and fiscal budget, and having apervasive impact <strong>on</strong> the ec<strong>on</strong>omy. 186Access to Housing as a Poverty Alleviati<strong>on</strong> Strategy.187 Decent and safe housing provides a stableplace <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> family activities; it enables the storage,preservati<strong>on</strong>, and preparati<strong>on</strong> of food; it is a fixedlocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> delivery of services such as waterand collecti<strong>on</strong> of household refuse <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> orderlydisposal; and, it serves as a protected place toguard possessi<strong>on</strong>s from envir<strong>on</strong>mental damage ortheft. 188 Loss of housing, tragic anywhere, can becatastrophic in the developing world. 189 Housingstability is a particularly important poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong>strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women. In developing ec<strong>on</strong>omiesthe home not <strong>on</strong>ly serves as shelter but alsois frequently a place <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business.Housing Finance. Analysis by UN-Habitat revealsthat the global housing needs cannot be met byaid or state subsidies al<strong>on</strong>e. Meeting the housingneeds of the world’s poor will require ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth (job and income generati<strong>on</strong>) and housingfinance. However, stimulating housing producti<strong>on</strong>and catalysing financial markets have other positiveeffects, that go bey<strong>on</strong>d the development of thehousing itself. In markets where financial instituti<strong>on</strong>sare not active because a market is untested,governments can leverage private sector financingby providing credit enhancement to support borrowers,developers or lenders; using subsidies judiciouslyto leverage financing, assuring transparency;and facilitating in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are manymodels of specialized programs that provide incentivesto financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s to lend to the poor aswell as to those who serve them. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> governmentcan play a catalytic role in bringing together theprivate sector and other instituti<strong>on</strong>s. 190Despite the obvious importance of housing producti<strong>on</strong>and its reliance <strong>on</strong> finance, the existingfinancing instruments to address the shelter needsof the poor are at a nascent stage. Existing instrumentsdo not fully resp<strong>on</strong>d to the reality of povertyor the need. 191 To meet the need, many countriesadopt housing policies, known as ‘filtering’ strate-107


Box 9 Singapore: importanceof workers’ CentralProvident FundUnder the scheme first instituted in 1955, employeesin Singapore are required by law to save a proporti<strong>on</strong>of their m<strong>on</strong>thly income in a central providentfund (CPF) account. Employers also make m<strong>on</strong>thlyc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s to their employees’ CPF account. Muchof these savings are invested in government securities,providing a cheap and ready source of financeto the government <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public housing c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>and nati<strong>on</strong>al capital <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also provide asource of mortgage financing at the individual levelto help home buyers meet their mortgage paymentswithout the need to dip into their cash reserves. Forthe average worker the m<strong>on</strong>thly repayment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thefl at is less than half of the CPF savings deposit.Sources: Yuen 2002, 2005.gies. 192 However, a key limitati<strong>on</strong> of a mortgagebasedfiltering strategy is that it has a l<strong>on</strong>g timehoriz<strong>on</strong> at best; and, a market-based filteringstrategy that is not matched with housing policiestargeted to the poor, will result in inequalities andleave the poor behind.Some countries have been extensively involved insetting housing goals and directly financing housing.Singapore, <strong>on</strong>ce characterised by vast squattersettlements, established a Housing and DevelopmentBoard (HDB) to finance and subsidisehousing developed by the state but c<strong>on</strong>structedby the private sector and then sold to homebuyers.Over 85 percent of Singaporeans live ingovernment-built housing. Singapore has emphasiseda homeownership strategy that has playeda key part in raising residents’ sense of bel<strong>on</strong>gingto the new living envir<strong>on</strong>ment.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are also many examples of developing nati<strong>on</strong>scommitted to meet their housing challengesand testing and developing a broad variety ofhousing policies. South Africa quickly startedoff with an impressive array of housing policyresp<strong>on</strong>ses, such as housing plans, fixed interestloan products, micro-loan financing, a securitisati<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>duit, and partnerships with financialinstituti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> country is still in the process ofexperimentati<strong>on</strong> and evaluati<strong>on</strong>, but the commitmentto its housing sector is clear. 193Public Private PartnershipsSeveral <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of public private partnerships(PPPs) were developed in the last two decadeswith built-in provisi<strong>on</strong>s of housing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepoor. This period saw the ec<strong>on</strong>omies of severaldeveloping countries booming and globalising,with a direct impact <strong>on</strong> cities like Sao Paolo,Mumbai, Delhi, Seoul, Kuala Lumpur, Manila andJakarta. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities created a hugedemand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> space <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> businesses and housing, inturn creating business opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the realestate sector, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> which it needed land in primelocati<strong>on</strong>s and land with trunk services in peripheralareas, both of which were scarce. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sameec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities meant a growing populati<strong>on</strong>of the poor who could af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d <strong>on</strong>ly in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malaccess to space in the city, with all its legal andenvir<strong>on</strong>mental insecurities. Pressures placedup<strong>on</strong> city development instituti<strong>on</strong>s, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,gave birth to public-private partnerships as <strong>on</strong>eapproach to solving problems affecting both thereal estate sector and the poor.Successful PPPs from which the poor have benefitedhave tended to rely <strong>on</strong> instruments of thestate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> trunk infrastructure that would ensureadequate timing of project development, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of new regulati<strong>on</strong>s and laws. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reare several examples where a combinati<strong>on</strong> of theseinstruments has been used to ensure legal/<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malaccess to land and housing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. GuidedLand Development has been implemented in the108


Box 10 Slum upgradinginitiative in Dali<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t,SenegalUpgrading of slums in Dali<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t has provided dwellersthere with new opportunities and better livingenvir<strong>on</strong>ment. A <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal land title has been granted tomore than 500 head of households including womenand their houses have been c<strong>on</strong>nected to the basicservices. Because of its proximity to the city centre,rent and land price have steadily risen, and thesettlement has seen rapid development of high-risehousing of good quality. Noticeable growth of newec<strong>on</strong>omic activities favoured by land security andmicrocredit facilities that have helped slum dwellersaccess start-up funding to initiate income generatingactivities that c<strong>on</strong>tributed to their ec<strong>on</strong>omicempowerment. Source: Diop 2007.periphery of cities like Seoul, Jakarta, Chennai,and Delhi, under c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s obliging private landownersto provide a certain percentage of smallplots which poor families can af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d. 194Transfer of Development Rights (TDR) is an effectiveinstrument applied in such projects to generatelow income housing <strong>on</strong> high value city landthrough the participati<strong>on</strong> of private landownersand developers. Private landowners, or developerswilling to build houses <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> existing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maldwellers, are given the right to build more thanthe permissible floor space index or floor arearatio specified in z<strong>on</strong>ing regulati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the plot.If possible, they can build additi<strong>on</strong>al space <strong>on</strong>the same plot or be allowed to transfer the developmentright to other plots in specified z<strong>on</strong>es. 195TDR works where there is a high premium <strong>on</strong>land and where the permissible density is highenough to leave surplus land after building lowincomehousing.Government as intermediary and facilitator betweenowners and low-income occupiers. In thecase of Land Sharing as used extensively in theIndian city of Hyderabad and to some extent inBangkok, Thailand, the Municipal Corporati<strong>on</strong> ofHyderabad and the nati<strong>on</strong>al Housing Authorityof Thailand largely play the role of intermediaries.Government authorities in those places helpto negotiate deals between owners of the landand its low-income occupiers. Once agreement isreached to share the land, the governments thenhelp the occupants to gain access to finance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>rebuilding housing in the porti<strong>on</strong> of land they areto occupy under the shared arrangement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fee<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registering the new ownership and transfer ofproperty is exempted by the government. 196 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>arrangement works in situati<strong>on</strong>s where the originallandowners have little hope of recovering theiroccupied property without prol<strong>on</strong>ged litigati<strong>on</strong>,and where getting even a part of the land backhas major advantages.Fostering Citizenship and <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentthrough C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>, In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> andParticipatory Property Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mOffering public educati<strong>on</strong> and legal aid regardingmarket structures to the poor is of critical importance,otherwise the effectiveness <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor ofthe above menti<strong>on</strong>ed measures of legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m,governance re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and market development canbe nullified. Multiple c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s, involvement ofsocial organisati<strong>on</strong>s in the c<strong>on</strong>tacting of propertyholders, well-publicised displays and provisi<strong>on</strong> ofmaterials to communities all c<strong>on</strong>tribute to satisfacti<strong>on</strong>and improved efficiency of property re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.In particular, active communicati<strong>on</strong> toward andparticipati<strong>on</strong> by civil society are important to ensurethe quality of systemic change in the propertyrights regime.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se mechanisms allow beneficiaries to havein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m’s framework, strategies,implementati<strong>on</strong> and targets as well as to109


Box 11 Peru regularises the process of titling propertywithin settlementsTo initiate the regularisati<strong>on</strong> process of property in eachsettlement, an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>al assembly was held toexplain details of the procedure, obtain approval of theassembly. Each assembly was required to designate itsown representatives. At this stage, problems such asmultiple or questi<strong>on</strong>able leadership groups were resolved.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se problems generally arose when there wasevidence of lack of representati<strong>on</strong> or when those havingdeveloped clientelistic links with municipal authoritiesassumed questi<strong>on</strong>able leadership. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> strategyemployed by Peru’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Formalisati<strong>on</strong>of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Property (COFOPRI) in breaking this patternwas to establish a direct link with the settler assembliesthemselves. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> assembly made it possible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the majority of the settlers to link directly with COFOPRIand to decide the best way to initiate the titling processand exercise their representati<strong>on</strong>. To this end, 3,500in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mative assemblies were held in 3,500 settlementsbetween 1996 and 2000.Between 1996 and 2001, some 2,274 settlements wereregularised in all of Peru, which represented <strong>on</strong>e milli<strong>on</strong>titled families. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> 6,000 in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mative and preparatoryassemblies held in this period are the clearest proofof the high level of citizen participati<strong>on</strong> in the process.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> meetings in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med settlers of the kind of documentati<strong>on</strong>needed by officials charged with creating the listof legal occupants. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> officials would visit the homesof settlers to explain how c<strong>on</strong>flicts and the lack of evidentiarydocuments might be resolved.To promote resp<strong>on</strong>sibility am<strong>on</strong>g officials in charge oftitling services, the parties resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> deliveringservices to each settlement were clearly identified, soresidents knew which officials were in charge. Unlikethe previous titling process, when <strong>on</strong>ly certain directorshad access to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> such as changes in titlingprocedures and the identity of the officials resp<strong>on</strong>sible,COFOPRI guaranteed the right of any pers<strong>on</strong> to receivein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about the titling process and to know theofficials in charge. Studies developed in 2000 to evaluatethe per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance of the Peruvian project c<strong>on</strong>firmedthat these participatory mechanisms raised the communitysupport and satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with the project.Source: Mosquiera, 2007.participate in specific stages of the planningand implementati<strong>on</strong> of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y expand thebeneficiaries’ capacity to participate, negotiate,influence, c<strong>on</strong>trol and hold accountable thepublic instituti<strong>on</strong>s in charge of property rightsre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and administrati<strong>on</strong>. On a broader scale,such measures integrate the positive elements ofproperty rules, such as allocati<strong>on</strong> of resp<strong>on</strong>sibilityand liability with the fostering of citizenship andsocial cohesi<strong>on</strong>. 197Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Policy Designand SequencingIt is advisable to integrate acti<strong>on</strong> projects regardingthe four building blocks of the propertysystem into a design that pays attenti<strong>on</strong> to additi<strong>on</strong>alelements:1. Build-in Research and Policy Analysis as wellas Piloting and Evaluati<strong>on</strong> Schemes ahead ofFull-scale Implementati<strong>on</strong>. A policy projectwith little policy analysis and research tocompare methodologies, prioritise areas andspecial measures, pilot innovati<strong>on</strong>s or evaluateitself will suffer from a slow instituti<strong>on</strong>allearning process and will risk to detect dysfuncti<strong>on</strong>slate. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> l<strong>on</strong>g-term sustainabilityof property re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms must be addressed early,al<strong>on</strong>gside with potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>flicts causedby re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m processes.110


2. Pay Attenti<strong>on</strong> to Sequencing. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>tentand sequence of a set of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m acti<strong>on</strong>s andthe setting of priorities will have to be left toc<strong>on</strong>text-based analysis in nati<strong>on</strong>al and localsettings. Formally however, it is important topoint to the fact that success of the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms ineach of the four building blocks of the propertysystem will depend not <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> the qualityof the individual measures taken but <strong>on</strong> thesequence in which they are taken. Getting thephasing right is as important as the c<strong>on</strong>tent ofthe individual measures. 1983. Issues of Sovereignty and Territorial Aut<strong>on</strong>omy,e.g. regarding indigenous people, must be assessedand tackled prior to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of propertyrights regimes, or restituti<strong>on</strong> or privatisati<strong>on</strong> insensitive areas. Otherwise the envisi<strong>on</strong>ed processwill be affected negatively, delayed or evennullified. 1994. On-the-Ground Assessments. Even if re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mmeasures are carried out diligently they maybe perceived as interventi<strong>on</strong>ist and top-downoriented by the poor. Property rights re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mprogrammes have often been successful wherealso based <strong>on</strong> the ground assessment of ownershipand family relati<strong>on</strong>s. Differences infamily and community structures and spatialorganisati<strong>on</strong> have to be identified at the fieldlevel (in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal marriages, de-facto headships,sp<strong>on</strong>taneous organisati<strong>on</strong> of public spaces,etc). In most c<strong>on</strong>texts this planning measurefacilitates the collecti<strong>on</strong> of reliable data aboutpossessi<strong>on</strong>s and functi<strong>on</strong>ing customs, it givesthe poor a sense of being taken seriously duringthe re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process, produces transparency inthe property rights’ definiti<strong>on</strong> processes, makesofficials more accountable to the process, c<strong>on</strong>tributesto the reducti<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>flicts am<strong>on</strong>gbeneficiaries, and might even create bottom-uppressure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> more legal and regulatory re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.5. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Art of the L<strong>on</strong>g Breath. A full scale re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m,including legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and parallel interventi<strong>on</strong>sin all four building blocks of the propertyrights system, cannot be carried out within thenormal cycle of democratic electi<strong>on</strong>s and hasto be sustained over several legislatures. Someindividual re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m benefits might be visiblerapidly, but sustained beneficial effects <strong>on</strong>lytake hold if property rights re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is sustainedand carried out over a l<strong>on</strong>g period of time. Onthe macro level, beneficial effects of propertyrights re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m will take hold over 10-15 years.Given this need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> l<strong>on</strong>g breath, enlightenedauthoritarian regimes seem to have an easiertask in property re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m than emerging ordeficient democracies. However, there areseveral ways in which property rights re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mcan be sustained over the normal life cycle ofa democratic government. One possibility isto promote re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms with broad support fromseveral parties and to make property re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ageneral interest grounded in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>.In order to overcome <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>midable oppositi<strong>on</strong>from powerful social actors against propertyre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, broad popular demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m fromcivil society and the private sector and str<strong>on</strong>gcoaliti<strong>on</strong>s of change are needed. Need assessment,awareness and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> campaignsam<strong>on</strong>g civil society and grass-roots movementsneed to be fostered to marginalize thepowerful gatekeepers of the status quo of vastextra-legality. This ought to be c<strong>on</strong>ceived asa multi-stakeholder ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t including media,business groups and associati<strong>on</strong>s of the poor,academia, and government agencies favourableto change.111


What can D<strong>on</strong>or Countries andMultilateralism do <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Promoti<strong>on</strong>of Property Rights of the Global Poor?<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> establishment of fully functi<strong>on</strong>al propertysystems and pro-poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is first and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emosta nati<strong>on</strong>al and local issue. It demands the renegotiati<strong>on</strong>of instituti<strong>on</strong>al, legal and social relati<strong>on</strong>sat nati<strong>on</strong>al and local levels. Assisting countriesand multilateral organisati<strong>on</strong>s are obligatednot to disrupt <strong>on</strong>going processes of renegotiati<strong>on</strong>.Further ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts of d<strong>on</strong>or countries are required todesign their own laws so that they do not aggravatethe problems of the world’s poorest. D<strong>on</strong>orcountries, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, need to deny giving safehaven to bank deposits by elites having lootedresources from the world’s poorest societies, andthey should actively work to prevent payment ofdomestic company bribes to public officials ofdeveloping countries. 200 Some advocate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> anactive role of internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s in domesticgovernance, circumventing domestic elitesand instituti<strong>on</strong>alising the necessary governancere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. 201 To date, there is little evidence tosuggest that it can make a noticeable difference.A better opti<strong>on</strong> is to make re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms more sustainableby coordinating and supporting broad re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mmeasures multilaterally. C<strong>on</strong>cern <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> l<strong>on</strong>ger-termendurance of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms is an important c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>,given that the c<strong>on</strong>cerns of individual governmentsmay be short-lived due to the fact thatthey are limited to short cycles of legislati<strong>on</strong>. Thisshould help to ensure that the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms will endureover the l<strong>on</strong>g term, something that individualgovernments, limited to short cycles of legislati<strong>on</strong>,may not normally be able to accomplish.A System of Multilateral Charters. One of themost important development ec<strong>on</strong>omists hasproposed a system of charters to legally empowerthe world’s poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> charters would set minimumstandards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> natural resource revenues to states,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> checks and balances in governance, budgettransparency, post c<strong>on</strong>flict management, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>investment. 202 Property rights are present anddeserve central attenti<strong>on</strong> in all these charters,since they could be decisive in making systemicproperty re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m sustainable.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> charter <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> natural resource revenue, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, would set minimum standards oftransparency and fair competiti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the aucti<strong>on</strong>ingof extracti<strong>on</strong> rights, diminish the price risk<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> government of poor countries, h<strong>on</strong>estly brokerin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about m<strong>on</strong>ey flows to government byextracti<strong>on</strong> companies, and set standards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> publicexpenditure of natural resource revenue — channellingit to domestic market development andcitizen-owned equity funds. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> charter <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> checksand balances would set limits to government and/or private m<strong>on</strong>opolies in the ownership and c<strong>on</strong>trolof media companies and regulate financing andspending in electi<strong>on</strong> campaigns. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> charter <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>budget transparency would commit governmentsto the m<strong>on</strong>thly publicati<strong>on</strong> of allocati<strong>on</strong> of assetsto government instituti<strong>on</strong>s in order to allow scrutinyfrom below and install intergovernmental peerreview mechanisms. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> charter <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> post-c<strong>on</strong>flictsituati<strong>on</strong>s would commit external security andlegal en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the l<strong>on</strong>g haul, set uptransparent budgetary processes and participatorygovernment, regulate property restituti<strong>on</strong> and thework rec<strong>on</strong>ciliati<strong>on</strong> commissi<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> investmentcharter would establish credibility by precludinggovernments from strategies of c<strong>on</strong>fiscati<strong>on</strong> andlimit extreme manipulati<strong>on</strong> of exchange rates, prices,and public utility charges. Instead of pushingre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m processes individually, like minded countriesmight also agree <strong>on</strong> some essential points ofa property systems re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m listed in this report andcommit to such re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in a charter, complementingthe other charters needed to link the world’smost poor to the chains of value additi<strong>on</strong>.112


Foster Coaliti<strong>on</strong>s of Change in Favour of EquitableProperty Systems. D<strong>on</strong>ors and internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>scan engage with domestic groups — suchas businesses, NGOs and grassroots movements ofpeasants and small-business owners — and enlisttheir support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property rights re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms in c<strong>on</strong>tactwith governments. Depending <strong>on</strong> the circumstances,fostering coaliti<strong>on</strong>s of change by such practicesmay potentially bear fruit. Success requiresl<strong>on</strong>g-term commitment by the parties, a str<strong>on</strong>glocal ownership, wide stakeholder participati<strong>on</strong>and good local management capacity. D<strong>on</strong>orcountries and multilateral instituti<strong>on</strong>s have animportant subsidiary role to play in areas of transnati<strong>on</strong>alin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> gathering and distributi<strong>on</strong>,educati<strong>on</strong>, and technical assistance. Multilateralorganisati<strong>on</strong>s have an important role to playin making the engagements of d<strong>on</strong>or countriesmore coherent and coordinated and in providingstandards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> intergovernmental peer review.Although there is now c<strong>on</strong>siderable awarenessof the importance of property rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor,failure to appreciate the historical roots, complexity,and political nature of the underlying issuescan give rise to recommendati<strong>on</strong>s that maynot <strong>on</strong>ly fail to do justice to the topic but couldalso prove to be unsustainable.Capacity Building and Technical Assistance.Given the c<strong>on</strong>text-specificity and politicallysensitive nature of property issues and to makeservices in this area accessible to a majority ofthe populati<strong>on</strong>, there is a significant need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>building capacity <strong>on</strong> both the technical andanalytical levels within the public sector as wellas am<strong>on</strong>g other agents who can be mobilised. Inthis domain, the internati<strong>on</strong>al community andd<strong>on</strong>or countries can provide trans-governmentalor multilaterally coordinated assistance in capacitybuilding leading to greater sustainabilityof re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m programmes.Seed-financing of Property Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. Functi<strong>on</strong>alproperty systems are self-sustainable. L<strong>on</strong>gstanding injecti<strong>on</strong> of aid from abroad would beseen as harmful to this goal or a symptom ofsystemic inadequacy. However, in the early stages,and depending <strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>text, many of theabove menti<strong>on</strong>ed re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms might be triggered bya combinati<strong>on</strong> of technical assistance and seedfinancingfrom abroad. Such projects should beaccompanied by clear terms of reference as tothe timetable and phases <strong>on</strong> the path to selfsustainability.Cross-country Land Policy Indicators. Althoughthe importance is widely recognised, it is oftendifficult to integrate land rights into policy dialogueor to dem<strong>on</strong>strate the seriousness of anissue due to the lack of comparable indicators.Experience in other sectors has shown that defininga simple set of indicators, some of whichcould be generated by the land administrati<strong>on</strong>system <strong>on</strong> a routine basis, could make it mucheasier to steer the policy dialogue towards criticalissues and at the same time to measureprogress over time. Such indicators should include:(1) coverage and accessibility of the system,potential and actual; (2) cost-effectivenessof service provisi<strong>on</strong>; (3) extent to which governmentholds or acquires land rights and the wayin which they are exercised, and (4) ways toaccess property through market and n<strong>on</strong>-marketchannels.Ranking Systems of Property Rights Af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ded toWomen. In the multilateral sphere, <strong>on</strong>e possibleapproach to addressing the problem of discriminati<strong>on</strong>of women in property matters would be to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulate a rigorous ranking system of propertyrights protecti<strong>on</strong> af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ded to women. Such anindex/ranking may focus attenti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> how differentcountries score in terms of en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement,protecti<strong>on</strong>, scope and depth of rights. Ranking113


ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts have proved useful in the ‘doing business’envir<strong>on</strong>ment. Property rights are a comp<strong>on</strong>entof World Bank rankings, but the propertyrights’ comp<strong>on</strong>ents are not gender-specific. Aseparate ranking may draw more attenti<strong>on</strong> to theissue and prompt improvement in the propertyrightsenvir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women.6. C<strong>on</strong>cluding Message<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> relevance of fair access to property rightsgoes way bey<strong>on</strong>d their role as ec<strong>on</strong>omic assets.Secure and accessible property rights provide asense of identity, dignity, and bel<strong>on</strong>ging to peopleof very different ec<strong>on</strong>omic means. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y createreliable ties of rights and obligati<strong>on</strong>s am<strong>on</strong>g communitymembers as well as a system of mutualrecogniti<strong>on</strong> of rights and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities bey<strong>on</strong>dthe local community. For many poor individualsand the communities in which they live, therelati<strong>on</strong>ship with property is more than just anaggregate of occupied and used plots. It is thevery expressi<strong>on</strong> of a way of life, and <strong>on</strong>e that theyshould have the opportunity to improve by virtueof their own ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts.114


Chapter 2 EndnotesUniversal Declarati<strong>on</strong> of Human Rights, Article 17, Provisi<strong>on</strong>s (1) and(2). Securing agreement <strong>on</strong> this <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong> required omitting the wordprivate be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e property. See Glend<strong>on</strong> 2001: 182-3.2 See Cheneval 2006.3 See Locke 1988; Wheeler 1980.4 See Cavallar 2002. This report understands private property rightsas a spectrum of ownership and usufruct rights that are not held by thestate and allocated to a an individual bearer or a corporate group ofbearers. In customary as well as advanced capitalist systems, privateproperty rights can be owned individually and in comm<strong>on</strong> by individualand corporative legal pers<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> working group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this Chapter isaware that this understanding runs c<strong>on</strong>trary to a noti<strong>on</strong> restricting theuse of the term ‘private property’ to individual freehold.5 Sachs (2006: 18) estimates that 2.5 billi<strong>on</strong> people currently live inpoverty in developing countries.6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se countries were Dominica, Grenada, Samoa, St. Lucia and St.Vincent and the Grenadines, all tiny island states in which issues ofproperty rights are signifi cantly smaller in scale than those in muchlarger countries. Of the 76 countries measured within the CPIA, <strong>on</strong>lySamoa scored an aggregate 4 out of 6 over the total 16 governanceindicators. 2005 IDA Resource Allocati<strong>on</strong> Index, Available at www.worldbank.org.7 World Bank, CPIA 2005 Assessment Questi<strong>on</strong>naire: 33, available atwww.worldbank.org.8 United Nati<strong>on</strong>s 1980.9 Woolf 1938.10 IFAD 2001: 86.11 Nielsen 2006: 204-219.12 Ravna 2006: 77.13 Estimates by the UN Human Settlements Program indicate that overthe next 25 years this fi gure will increase by more than 2 billi<strong>on</strong> people.14 Sachs 2006: 27.15 Building <strong>on</strong> a body of recent literature, the 2005 IFAD report <strong>on</strong>rural development defi nes an asset (also called ‘capital’, ‘stock’, or ‘endowment’)as ‘anything that can be used, without being used up, toincrease regular returns above receipts from labour, whether hired orself-employed, and thus enhance producers’ income of c<strong>on</strong>sumers’ welfare.Typical assets are land, wells, cattle, tools, houses, shares, skills,health and roads.’16 de Soto 2000.17 Detailed in Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001.18 Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001.19 Even in countries where government may be relied up<strong>on</strong> to stay withinthe boundaries of the law, overly flexible terminology leads to opportunity<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public purpose to turn into private purpose as recent cases in the USSupreme Court illustrate. This is even more important <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the global poorwho often live where there is limited residual faith in governments keepingto the spirit of the law.20 Hart 1961.21 European <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> 2007: 4.22 Mosqueira 2007: 7.23 IFAD 2001: 88.24 IFAD 2001: 88.25 UN-HABITAT 2005a: 107.26 CLEP In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses India: 10.27 See Collier 2007: 140-146.28 See Garcia-Bolivar 2007.29 See Prahalda 2005: 87-88.30 See Mendoza 2006: 17.31 South African Institute of Internati<strong>on</strong>al Affairs 2005.32 USAID 2007 terms it the ‘substantive dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of legal empowerment’.33 Terminology is never unifi ed. Defi niti<strong>on</strong>al guidance, also bey<strong>on</strong>d Africa,is given in: Land Tenure Lexic<strong>on</strong> 2000.34 See Cotula 2007.35 See World Development Report 2002: 9.36 Populati<strong>on</strong> Reference Bureau 2005.37 UN-HABITAT 2005b: Chapter 1.38 Alden Wily 2006c: 1739 FAO 2007.40 This has been largely the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the thirty or so wars of the lastseveral decades from Cambodia to Chile, Bosnia to Zimbabwe, Afghanistanto Peru. It has been uni<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mly the case in the regi<strong>on</strong> where civil warshave been most numerous over the last two decades, Sub-Saharan Africa.(Richards 2005; Currey 2004)41 Sudan Comprehensive Peace Agreement, January 2005 and InterimNati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, Sudan, 2005. Alden Wily 2007.42 Hurwitz et al. 200543 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> land and product values of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>est resources is immense, mildlyindicative in <strong>on</strong>ly the recorded global timber trading values of US$354billi<strong>on</strong> in 2000, the US$5.56 trilli<strong>on</strong> import value of n<strong>on</strong>-timber <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>estproducts in 2002 (from brazil nuts to gum arabica) and the already milli<strong>on</strong>sof dollars being expended that year in trading carb<strong>on</strong> credits from<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>est stocks. FAO 2005.44 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir share of income capture from commercial logging and paperproducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example has been minimal to n<strong>on</strong>-existent to date (e.g.Liberia, Papua New Guinea, Nepal, Brazil). FAO 2005; Colchester et al.2001.45 C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are particularly severe in Africa, the Middle East andSouth Asia. See World Bank 2004a: 1.46 See Hodgs<strong>on</strong> 2004.47 United Nati<strong>on</strong>s 1980: 8. This old fi gure is not based <strong>on</strong> rigorousmeasurement. In some more recent studies even lower percentages areindicated. See FAO 1999. Women’s right to land and natural resources:some implicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a human-rights based approach. SD Dimensi<strong>on</strong>s115


(<strong>on</strong> fi le at FAO: http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LTan0025.htm).48 Nielsen 2006: 206; CLEP Uganda: 21, CLEP Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, CLEP Philippines,CLEP Sri Lanka: 13.49 Ann Whitehead and Dzodzi Tsikata 2003: 77.50 Izumi 2007.51 Agarwal 1994.52 ICRW 2005: 3.53 Quisumbing and Maluccio 2000.54 Not always, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, Inuit are 85 percent of the semi-aut<strong>on</strong>omousGreenland regi<strong>on</strong> of Denmark. Indigenous people represent half or morecitizens of Guatemala, Peru and especially Bolivia.55 In 1972 the UN <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Group <strong>on</strong> Indigenous Populati<strong>on</strong>s accepteda defi niti<strong>on</strong>, amended in 1983 and 1986. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> No. 169 in1989 accepted a broader defi niti<strong>on</strong>, embodied in the UN Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>the Rights of Indigenous Peoples.56 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are people in other regi<strong>on</strong>s regulating their land relati<strong>on</strong>sthrough indigenous norms. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are mainly members of indigenous minorities,such as Native Americans in North America, Sami in the northernpolar areas of Europe and Russia and native peoples of Australiaand New Zealand. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are excluded here mainly because comparativelyextremely few of their number are defi nitively ‘poor’.57 Kaelin 2006: 175.58 An estimated 25 milli<strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>s have been displaced by armedc<strong>on</strong>fl ict in more than 40 countries. In Africa, the number of IDPs reaches13.2 milli<strong>on</strong>, in Central and South America 3.7 milli<strong>on</strong>, in Asia 3.3 milli<strong>on</strong>,in Europe 3 milli<strong>on</strong>, and in the Middle East 2.1 milli<strong>on</strong>. In 2004, thelargest internal displacement situati<strong>on</strong>s were Sudan (5-6 milli<strong>on</strong> IDPs),Colombia (2 - 3 milli<strong>on</strong>), DRC (2.3 milli<strong>on</strong>), Uganda (up to 2 milli<strong>on</strong>),and Iraq (over 1 milli<strong>on</strong>). Sudan, Uganda, Colombia, Iraq, Somalia, andNepal were the scene of major new displacement during the same year,whereas DRC, Angola, Southern Sudan, Liberia, Burundi, and CentralAfrican Republic saw major return movements. (Norwegian RefugeeCouncil, Global IDP Project, Internal Displacement — Global Overviewof Trends and Developments in 2004, Geneva March 2005: 5-6, 10.)59 Drawn from Kaelin 2006.60 See Handbook <strong>on</strong> Housing and Property Restituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Refugees andDisplaced Pers<strong>on</strong>s 2007.61 Acemoglu et al. 2004; Acemoglu and Johns<strong>on</strong> 2005; de Soto 1989,2000; Roll and Talbott 2001.62 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> proporti<strong>on</strong> of owners resisting expropriati<strong>on</strong> against marketvalue compensati<strong>on</strong> is high. In a case reported by Galiani and Schargrodsky(2004: 5) the proporti<strong>on</strong> is 5 resisting to 8 agreeing.63 See Chapter 1, Secti<strong>on</strong> 2; de Soto 1989: 201-230.64 See de Soto 2000: 200-202.65 See USAID 2007: 21-23.66 Gradstein 2006.67 Ch<strong>on</strong>g and Gradstein 2007b show that inequality subverts egalitarianproperty rights systems.68 ‘…the initial c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s had lingering effects, not <strong>on</strong>ly becausecertain fundamental characteristics of New World ec<strong>on</strong>omies were difficult to change, but also because government policies and instituti<strong>on</strong>stended to reproduce them. Specifi cally, in those societies that beganwith extreme inequality, elites were better able to establish a legalframework that insured them disproporti<strong>on</strong>ate shares of political power,and to use that greater infl uence to establish rules, laws, and othergovernment policies that advantaged members of the elites relative t<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong>-members — c<strong>on</strong>tributing to persistence over time of the high degreeof inequality.’ (Sokoloff and Engerman 2000).69 Coudouel et al. 2007: 6.70 Ch<strong>on</strong>g and Gradstein 2007a; Dabla-Norris et al. 2007.71 Acemoglu and Robins<strong>on</strong> 2005.72 Gradstein 2006; Deininger and Squire 1998.73 Ch<strong>on</strong>g and Gradstein 2007.74 USAID 2007.75 Jacoby and Minten 2005.76 Major comparative reviews of evidence of impacts <strong>on</strong> investmentand access to credit suggest that titling and registrati<strong>on</strong> of land is mostlikely to be effective where robust <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal fi nancial markets already existand where there are incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> investment created by factorssuch as proximity to urban markets and good quality land (Bruce andMigot-Adholla 1994; Feder and Nishio (1996). Studies that particularlyfocus <strong>on</strong> the poor suggest that credit and other benefi ts may be heavilyskewed toward large landholders (Carter and Olinto 2003).77 Almost never occurs outside developed countries: Okoth Ogendo1999; Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001; Hunt 2004.78 For example, in India, the amount of bribes paid every year by usersof land administrati<strong>on</strong> services is estimated at US$700 milli<strong>on</strong> (TransparencyInternati<strong>on</strong>al India 2005), three-quarters of the public spending<strong>on</strong> science, technology, and envir<strong>on</strong>ment.79 China was the fi rst centrally planned ec<strong>on</strong>omy to link the collectivesystem to household size farms. Households were allowed to c<strong>on</strong>tracttheir share of the collective land and cultivate it individually, inreturn paying to the collective a fi xed amount of produce, taxes andfees (Household Resp<strong>on</strong>sibility System). In a fi rst stage, results wereimpressive as China’s grain producti<strong>on</strong> increased from 321.2 milli<strong>on</strong>t<strong>on</strong>s in 1979 to 407.1 milli<strong>on</strong> t<strong>on</strong>s in 1984 (a fi ve-year increase of 27percent, or 5.4 percent a year). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> increase slowed down afterwards to469.5 milli<strong>on</strong> t<strong>on</strong>s in 2004. Further gains seem more diffi cult to achieve.More investment and access to credit is required in order to improve irrigati<strong>on</strong>,drainage, land terracing, soil upgrades, etc. Today, the Chinesefarmers’ use rights suffer from land grabbing by offi cials or by frequentand unpredictable readjustments of land rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number of sticksin farmer’s property rights bundle is still insuffi cient; the practice ofland readjustment has been the main source of land tenure insecurityin China since the decollectivisati<strong>on</strong> of agriculture. Farmers are there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eunwilling to make productivity-enhancing investments that wouldrequire several years to recover, such as irrigati<strong>on</strong>, drainage, or landterracing. See Prosterman 2006: 113. In 1998 the Government of Tajikistan,with the support of the World Bank, began the implementati<strong>on</strong>of the Farm Privatizati<strong>on</strong> Support Project (FPSP). Ten farms covering anarea of 17,000 hectares were privatised to individual families. First,farms were divided into their c<strong>on</strong>stituent brigades and per capita landwas divided am<strong>on</strong>g farmers. Inheritable but not tradable land use certificates were provided by the state land committee to individual farm-116


ers, refl ecting the allocati<strong>on</strong> of lands. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, water user associati<strong>on</strong>swere <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med and a community-managed water provisi<strong>on</strong> system, a watercharge collecti<strong>on</strong> mechanism, and maintenance of the intra-farmwater distributi<strong>on</strong> system were established. Third, a grant of US$300per hectare was provided to farmers to obtain crop inputs or any farmneeds to start farming as an independent family farmer. Fourth, technicalassistance was provided to farmers by using dem<strong>on</strong>strati<strong>on</strong> plots.In Tajikistan the government owns the land, but its use right is vestedwith the Tajik citizen, family, individual, or group of individuals. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>land use right is inheritable but this right cannot be rented, leased,transferred to n<strong>on</strong>-family members, mortgaged, or sold. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> land useright is registered and is backed by the government. In the case of theFPSP, land tenure rights are now vested with the farmer; in case of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merprivatisati<strong>on</strong> programmes, land use rights are collective, with thefarm manager making decisi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> behalf of the members. This differenceresults in different incentive structures and differential impacts ofindividual land tenure and collective land tenure <strong>on</strong> the incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>and incomes of farmers. Sattar and Mohib 2007: 463-465.80 Alden Wily 2006.81 See Mendoza 2006.82 Izumi 2007: 14.83 Bruce et al. 2006: 47-51.84 Alden Wily and Mbaya 2001; Alden Wily 2003; Alden Wily 2006 passim.85 Hardin 1968.86 Bruce and Migot-Adholla 1994; Mighot-Adholla et al. 1994a; Collierand Gunning 1999.87 Alden Wily 2006.88 Alden Wily 2002.89 Bruce and Migto-Adholla 1994; Deininger 2003; Augustinus 2003.90 Alden Wily 2002, 2006b, 2006c.91 Deininger et al. 2007.92 See Bruce et al. 2006: 107-142.93 CLEP Kenya; CLEP Pakistan; CLEP Philippines; CLEP Uganda.94 Field 2004.95 Deininger and Chamorro 2004; Bruce and Migot-Adholla 1994; Jacobyand Minten 2005.96 Bruce and Migot-Adholla 1994; Feder and Nishio 1996.97 Feder, Onchan and Raparia 1988; Galiani and Schargrodsky 200498 In Cambodia, people pay US$200 to $300 and more in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malfees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> title to land in urban areas. See World Bank 2002: 7.99 Augustinus 2003: 25.100 Palmer 1998: 87.101 Burns 2006: 3.102 In Mexico, ‘some ejidos prefer not to regularize the land <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> humansettlements to evade paying the land tax, which obviously promotes in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malityin land markets’ (UN-Habitat 2005a: 107). A similar outcomeis reported from Pakistan, rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxes to be set ataf<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable levels and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the revenue to fi nance services people wantand are willing to pay <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> (Payne 1997: 8).103 In Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, property tax re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m increased revenues under reducedadministrative and compliance costs. Careful introducti<strong>on</strong> of thechanges minimized resistance. Political will was a paramount requirement.Although there were pre-existing property taxes, dramatic adjustmentswere required to deliver the changes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se were carefully pilotedto test and improve procedures, to train staff and identify taxpayerresp<strong>on</strong>ses to the changes. Ind<strong>on</strong>esia’s tertiary educati<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>snow train about 600 property tax administrators a year. Colombia’s useof the self-assessment method has resulted in an increased tax baseand revenues and has allowed the cadastre to be updated. In Kenya, theprimary obstacles to property tax re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m have been lack of political willand weak administrati<strong>on</strong>. Taxpayers need to perceive the linkage withimproved local services and also need to be c<strong>on</strong>fi dent of fair administrati<strong>on</strong>.For an overview see Bird and Slack 2002104 C<strong>on</strong>dominium is another <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of housing tenure. It is the legalterm used in the United States and in most provinces of Canada <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> atype of joint ownership of real property in which porti<strong>on</strong>s of the propertyare comm<strong>on</strong>ly owned and other porti<strong>on</strong>s are individually owned. In Australiaand the Canadian province of British Columbia, the legal term <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>this is ‘strata title’. In Quebec, it is known as syndicates of co-ownership.In the United Kingdom, the equivalent is comm<strong>on</strong>hold, but this<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of ownership was <strong>on</strong>ly introduced in 2004.105 See Deininger et al. 2007.106 See e.g. Payne 2002; Durand-Lasserve 2003.107 See Galiani and Schargrodsky 2004. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors study a naturalexperiment whereby land titling was ex post granted to a large group ofindividual squatters. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> analysis reveals marked changes in ec<strong>on</strong>omicresp<strong>on</strong>ses of this group relatively to the c<strong>on</strong>trolled group of squatters.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> study shows <strong>on</strong>ly modest positive effect of land titling <strong>on</strong> accessto mortgage credit, and no impact <strong>on</strong> access to other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of credit.It shows no effect <strong>on</strong> the labour income of the households holding newtitles. However, it is shown that moving a poor household from uncertainusufructuary rights to a more complete bundle of property rightssubstantially increased investment in the family houses. Land titlingreduced the size of families. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se smaller families invested more inthe educati<strong>on</strong> of their children. In sum, entitling the poor increases theirinvestment both in the house and in the human capital of their children.This is a very c<strong>on</strong>crete example of legal empowerment with positive l<strong>on</strong>gterm effects. Property rights c<strong>on</strong>tribute to human development under anintergenerati<strong>on</strong>al and behavioural perspective.108 On Africa see a series of reports by IIED at: http://www.iied.org/NR/drylands/projects/landregistrati<strong>on</strong>.html109 Ejido land in Mexico, which can be trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med into fully alienablefreehold land based <strong>on</strong> a qualifi ed vote by the assembly, is a goodexample. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fact that <strong>on</strong>ly about a tenth of ejidos chose to go this routeillustrates that, even at high levels of per capita income, many userssee benefi ts from maintaining communal relati<strong>on</strong>s to be greater thanthose from full individualisati<strong>on</strong> of rights.110 Cotula 2007111 ‘Land Tenure Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and Gender Equality,’ UNRISD Researchand Policy Brief 4 (January, 2006) 1. In most Indian states the patta,or leasehold right over government land occupied by the poor is givenjointly in the name of the husband and wife. In Andhra Pradesh, thepatta is in the name of women <strong>on</strong>ly. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re have not been any studies <strong>on</strong>117


the outcomes or impacts of this practice. Banerjee 1999..112 UN-HABITAT 2006; Strickland 2004.113 Deere and Le<strong>on</strong> 2003.114 UN-HABITAT 2006.115 Agarwal 1994: 272.116 Drawn from Baechtold 2006.117 C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Biological Diversity (CBD) of June 5, 1992, http://www.biodiv.org/c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>/articles.asp118 http://www.wipo.int/freepublicati<strong>on</strong>s/en/tk/920/wipo_pub_920.pdf119 http://www.wipo.int/tk/en/laws/pdf/suigeneris_folklore.pdf120 http://www.wipo.int/edocs/mdocs/tk/en/wipo_grtkf_ic_9/wipo_grtkf_ic_9_inf_4.pdf121 For related aspects of bureaucratic justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor see Chapter1, Secti<strong>on</strong> 3.122 Ibid.123 CLEP Ind<strong>on</strong>esia; CLEP Sri Lanka: 27; CLEP Philippines.124 In Peru, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, particularly those that required c<strong>on</strong>gressi<strong>on</strong>alapproval of laws, were promoted with the active participati<strong>on</strong> of beneficiaries.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> proposal to modify the Civil Code to permit the administrative,rather than judicial, declarati<strong>on</strong> of adverse possessi<strong>on</strong> wasmet with a political debate based <strong>on</strong> different academic positi<strong>on</strong>s. Tothe extent to which the defi niti<strong>on</strong> depended <strong>on</strong> a legislative opti<strong>on</strong> andrequired political support, COFOPRI disseminated the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m proposalam<strong>on</strong>g the leaders of the settlements who would benefit from it and facilitatedthe organisati<strong>on</strong> of the leadership to defend the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m proposalsbe<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e C<strong>on</strong>gress. A group of leaders lobbied members of C<strong>on</strong>gress ofdiverse political sectors in order to dem<strong>on</strong>strate that the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms wouldbenefi t more than 100,000 families <strong>on</strong>ly in Lima, which was incentiveenough to obtain c<strong>on</strong>gressi<strong>on</strong>al approval.125 Through the interventi<strong>on</strong> of COFOPRI it was determined that theleaders would work with the technical staff of the instituti<strong>on</strong> to obtainthe technical and legal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> needed to carry out the requiredacti<strong>on</strong>s. In this stage legal obstacles to the regularisati<strong>on</strong> of propertyin favour of its occupants would be identifi ed, such as cases of privateproperty, archaeological land, or in a risk z<strong>on</strong>e. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong>of leaders enabled the settlers to appreciate the diffi culties that COFO-PRI c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>ted in regularising properties, made their expectati<strong>on</strong>s morerealistic regarding the time required to c<strong>on</strong>clude the delivery of titlingservices, and made them aware about the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms and complementaryacti<strong>on</strong>s.126 In Peru, COFOPRI developed the capacity to c<strong>on</strong>tinuously improvere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms through a series of incremental changes based <strong>on</strong> a learningby-doingapproach. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> drafting of new laws was linked to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>processes (0, 1 and 2) which ensured that experiences and less<strong>on</strong>slearned at the fi eld level were incorporated into the normative framework.For example, as the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> process advanced, COFOPRI,through inputs from fi eld staff and community representatives, uncoverednew <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality that were not identifi ed in the pilot project,like ‘pueblos tradici<strong>on</strong>ales’ (ancient in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements in Arequipa).COFOPRI and RPU worked together to develop legally sound and effi cientsoluti<strong>on</strong>s to these problems. New procedures were developed and testedat the organisati<strong>on</strong>al level and <strong>on</strong>ce validated, incorporated into thelegal framework.127 See FAO 2007. For general issues of public administrati<strong>on</strong> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msee Chapter 1, Secti<strong>on</strong> 3.128 Also recommended in CLEP Philippines, Ethiopia, Kenya, Uganda,Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, Tanzania, Sri Lanka.129 See Chapter 1, passim.130 Center of Advanced Study 2007: 122.131 World Bank, World Development Report 2002: 14.132 Computerising records in the Indian state of Karnataka undera PPP model is estimated to have saved users US$16 milli<strong>on</strong> in bribes(Lobo and Balakrishnan 2002). Automating registrati<strong>on</strong> and the associatedland valuati<strong>on</strong> allowed outsourcing to the private sector whichsignifi cantly improved access and resulted in cuts in stamp duty from14 percent to 8 percent while quadrupling tax revenue from US$120 toUS$480 milli<strong>on</strong>.133 See Prahalad 2005: 87-88.134 See FAO 2007: 25. See e.g. CLEP Uganda, Grassroots Academy,Property Secti<strong>on</strong>; CLEP Ethiopia (p.11 ss.) analyses how the current landsystem with state ownership gives the state (i.e. the individuals c<strong>on</strong>trollingthe state) immense power over peasants.135 Fernandes 2006.136 FAO 2007: 50.137 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Singapore urban planning experience dem<strong>on</strong>strates that giventhe will and effi ciency of implementati<strong>on</strong>, it is possible to plan aheadand promote organised growth. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> unauthorized settlements of Delhi,India, that are regularised in the late 1970s offer another example.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se settlements have seen signifi cant improvement following regularisati<strong>on</strong>due to implementati<strong>on</strong> of layout plans and extensi<strong>on</strong> of civicservices by government agencies. Residents there have come to acquirefull tenurial security, resulting in their making further investments atindividual and community levels and improving the quality of the microenvir<strong>on</strong>ment.In Malaysia, the government sets a ceiling price <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> lowcost housing, at RM25,000 per unit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> people with household income ofless than RM750 per m<strong>on</strong>th and requires the private sector to c<strong>on</strong>structlow cost housing (30 percent quota provisi<strong>on</strong>) in every residential development.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se urban planning ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts need to be made more widelyreplicated at the community and city level. Yuen 2002, 2004, 2005.138 Jacobs 1961; Newman 1972.139 Barzel 1997; Alexander 2001.140 Steuteville 2005; C<strong>on</strong>gress <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the New Urbanism 1999.141 CLEP Report from South America (Brazil).142 Santiago 2004.143 Banerjee 2005.144 Government of India 1998.145 Government of India 1998.146 An external evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the scheme showed that the 2,800families have improved their housing situati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siderably and haveorganised themselves to procure infrastructure incrementally. 600families have been gainfully employed in the home-based carpet weav-118


ing industry through the scheme. (Siddiqui and Khan 1994; UN-HABITAT1991).147 Govt. of India 2004.148 See Chapter 4, which covers this topic.149 For instance, in the city of Uttaradit, the initiative started withsurvey mapping of all the slums and small pockets of squatters, identifyinglandowners and those slums that could stay and that neededto be relocated. This helped link community organisati<strong>on</strong>s and beganbuilding a community network supported by young architects, a groupof m<strong>on</strong>ks and the mayor. Together, they sought to fi nd housing soluti<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1000 families within the existing city fabric through differenttechniques such as land sharing, re-blocking, in-situ upgrading andrelocati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir city-wide housing plan became the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cityupgrading programme under Baan Mank<strong>on</strong>g and now includes infrastructureimprovements, urban regenerati<strong>on</strong>, canal cleaning, wastelandreclamati<strong>on</strong> and park development. Bo<strong>on</strong>yabancha 2005.150 For a broader discussi<strong>on</strong> of this issue see Chapter 1, secti<strong>on</strong> 4.151 Brustinow 2006.152 Handbook <strong>on</strong> Housing and Property Restituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Refugees andDisplaced Pers<strong>on</strong>s 2007.153 Krant<strong>on</strong> and Swamy 1999; World Bank 2003.154 Although their initial level of income and assets was not significantly different from the average, their level of assets and incomein 1999 was more than 50 percent above the mean while their level ofc<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> was about 20 percent above the average.155 Deininger et al. 2007b.156 Rolfes 2006: 127-128.157 Bledsoe 2006.158 See Prahalad 2005; Kasturi Rangan et al. 2007.159 Apasco, a Mexican subsidiary of Holcim, realised that sellingcement through a chain of middlemen dramatically raises prices. Byopening new distributi<strong>on</strong> centres in remote areas where cement couldbe purchased bag-by-bag and providing technical and safety advice tobuilders, Apasco was able to sell resp<strong>on</strong>sibly to the poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> benefi ts tothe local communities included a facilitated access to building materialsat af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable prices. Apasco staff also offered c<strong>on</strong>sulting services<strong>on</strong> do-it-yourself building techniques. Less<strong>on</strong>s learned in Mexico arebeing studied at headquarters to see if this model can be replicatedelsewhere. (Source: WBCSD 2005: 47)160 WBCSD 2005.161 Delta Café buys raw materials from poor communities in EastTimor, creating sustainable livelihoods and gaining market rewards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>producing a socially resp<strong>on</strong>sible product. Delta Café is part of the NabeiroGroup of food companies, and is the market leader <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> coffee inPortugal, with a market share of 38 percent. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> company developedthe Delta Timor brand and marketed it as socially resp<strong>on</strong>sible coffeeafter getting involved with the growing communities in the remotehills of East Timor, a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer Portuguese col<strong>on</strong>y. This project is alreadyturning a profi t, thanks to the popularity of the new Delta Timor brandam<strong>on</strong>g Portuguese c<strong>on</strong>sumers, promoted str<strong>on</strong>gly by its partner S<strong>on</strong>ae,the country’s biggest retailer. Delta welcomes competiti<strong>on</strong> in the regi<strong>on</strong>from other coffee-producing companies, as this will improve the coffeeproducing techniques of all farmers. (Source: WBCSD 2005: 50.)162 Through its Solar Rural Operati<strong>on</strong>s, Shell Solar is bringing solarelectricity and equipment directly to remote households in six developingcountries (India, Sri Lanka, Philippines, South Africa, China, andMorocco). In Sri Lanka a typical solar electricity system powers sevenlights and sells <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> around $550-600. With 10,000 units sold by ShellSolar, benefi ts have included: 300 new jobs, mostly in rural areas;signifi cant reducti<strong>on</strong> in undesirable emissi<strong>on</strong>s by replacing kerosenelamps and diesel generators; bright light, making reading, cooking, andeducati<strong>on</strong> easier; and c<strong>on</strong>venient power to c<strong>on</strong>nect with the world viatelevisi<strong>on</strong> and radio. This distributi<strong>on</strong> model works, reaching break-evenin 2001. Two barriers were overcome: availability of systems and theability of householders to pay. (Source: WBCSD 2005: 58.)163 BP: Focusing <strong>on</strong> the macroec<strong>on</strong>omic impact of its operati<strong>on</strong>s, BPis working with the government in Trinidad and Tobago to encouragewider business ownership. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> aim is both to promote good governanceand to create a pool of businesses that can not <strong>on</strong>ly supply BP’s operati<strong>on</strong>sthere but also compete <strong>on</strong> a world scale, bey<strong>on</strong>d the present gasboom. Trinidad and Tobago is the largest liquefi ed natural gas (LNG)exporter to the United States, and BP aims to double its share of globalLNG business by 2010. Helping locally-owned c<strong>on</strong>tractors develop globalscale capabilities and become signifi cant part of BP’s current supplychain c<strong>on</strong>tributes to the government’s aim of achieving a dynamic andsustainable ec<strong>on</strong>omy through the building of knowledge-based skills.This will in turn allow the overall ec<strong>on</strong>omy to c<strong>on</strong>tinually evolve and recreateitself bey<strong>on</strong>d oil and gas. Success will also allow the governmentand people to see themselves, perhaps <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fi rst time, not merely asexporters of gas, but exporters of intellectual capital. This could becomereality as a result of local learning instituti<strong>on</strong>s, work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce and companiesbecoming global experts in the industry. Source: WBCSD 2005: 53.164 CLEP In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses India: 10.165 See also CLEP Uganda: 22; Guyers 2005; Chanell 2006.166 USAID 2006. In Nigeria, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance, <strong>on</strong>ly 10 percent of whatcan be used as collateral in the US can legally be used as collateral.This means that Nigerians have a thinner and less valuable bundle ofproperty rights in moveable and intangible property. A poor woman inCambodia may well have a crop in the fi eld or a pig or cow in a pasture.If she is able to use these to obtain a lawful loan she has <strong>on</strong>e additi<strong>on</strong>alcredit opti<strong>on</strong>. If she can use the moveable property she owns as collateralshe is likely to be offered a lower interest rate and better terms fromthe lender than if the loan was unsecured. If lenders are legally able toaccept such property as collateral she is also less likely to have to resortto an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal m<strong>on</strong>eylender when she needs credit.167 Savafi an, Fleisig and Steinbuks 2006. For example, in Bolivia,Bancosol offers borrowers who use collateral larger loans, l<strong>on</strong>ger loanterms, and lower interest rates than they do borrowers without collateral.In Romania, after a new collateral law was enacted in 2000the interest rate dropped by 6 percent and the interest rate <strong>on</strong> lendingdropped by 20 percent.168 IADB 2005, Unlocking Credit.169 USAID 2006: 4.170 USAID 2006: 5.171 Source: Grameen Bank.172 Critics are sceptical about the repayment fi gure and charge that119


the system leads to the borrower becoming dependent <strong>on</strong> the loans. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>bank has also been criticised <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the level of interest rates that climb ashigh as 20 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> loans to businesses that generate income. (Internati<strong>on</strong>alHerald Tribune, Asia-Pacifi c, Oct 13, 2006). Current amountof outstanding loans stands at TK 33.42 billi<strong>on</strong> (US$484.29 milli<strong>on</strong>).During the past 12 m<strong>on</strong>ths (April 06 to March 07) Grameen Bank disbursedTk. 50.42billi<strong>on</strong> (US$727.85 milli<strong>on</strong>). Projected disbursement <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>2007 is Tk 65.00 billi<strong>on</strong> (US$930 milli<strong>on</strong>), i.e. m<strong>on</strong>thly disbursement ofTk 5.42 billi<strong>on</strong> (US$77.50 milli<strong>on</strong>). End of the year outstanding loan isprojected to be at Tk. 40.00 billi<strong>on</strong> (US$572 milli<strong>on</strong>).173 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se companies have the following loan liability to GrameenBank :Grameen Fund : Tk 373.2 milli<strong>on</strong> (US$6.38 milli<strong>on</strong>); GrameenKrishi Foundati<strong>on</strong> : Tk 19 milli<strong>on</strong> (US$.33 milli<strong>on</strong>); Grameen Motsho(Fisheries) Foundati<strong>on</strong> : Tk 15 milli<strong>on</strong> (US$.26 milli<strong>on</strong>); Grameen Bankprovided guarantees in favour of the following organisati<strong>on</strong>s while theywere receiving loans from the government and the fi nancial organisati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se guarantees are still in effect. Grameen Shakti : Tk 9 milli<strong>on</strong>(US$0.12 milli<strong>on</strong>); Grameen Motsho (Fisheries) Foundati<strong>on</strong> : Tk 8 milli<strong>on</strong>(US$0.11 milli<strong>on</strong>); Grameen Kalyan; Grameen Kalyan (well-being) is aspin off company created by Grameen Bank.174 Source: Grameen Bank.175 Drawn from Garcia-Bolivar 2007.176 Studies in the Dominican Republic, Nicaragua, and Vietnam showthat insecure land ownership reduced the propensity to rent and limitedtransacti<strong>on</strong>s to pre-existing social networks, despite the associatedineffi ciency. See Macours/de Janvry and Sadoulet 2005; Deininger andChamorro 2004; Deininger and Jin 2003. Fear of losing the land, togetherwith explicit rental restricti<strong>on</strong>s, was the main reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> suboptimalper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance of rental markets in Ethiopia (Deininger, Ayalew and Alemu2006).177 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> case of China illustrates that, in the c<strong>on</strong>text of broad-basedland access, guaranteed l<strong>on</strong>g term rent can provide greatly enhanceefficiency while at the same time providing a basic social safety net ata cost that is much below alternative government programems, therebyallowing government to spend scarce resources <strong>on</strong> provisi<strong>on</strong> of productiveinfrastructure instead of safety nets. Also, having their basic subsistenceensured allows Chinese households to take <strong>on</strong> greater risks inn<strong>on</strong>-agricultural businesses and, with policies to foster lease markets<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> land, c<strong>on</strong>tributes signifi cantly to the emergence of a vibrant n<strong>on</strong>farmec<strong>on</strong>omy.178 See also CLEP Sri Lanka: 27-28; CLEP Tanzania.179 Banerjee and Iyer 2005; Nugent and Robins<strong>on</strong> 2002.180 Bruce 2006: 47-51.181 Bird and Slack 2006.182 CLEP Kenya, CLEP Uganda, CLEP Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, CLEP Philippines;Deininger et al. 2006.183 For a more detailed analysis and recommendati<strong>on</strong>s see Chapter1, Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 of this report. Evidence from Uganda suggests that greaterknowledge of laws providing tenure security to customary tenure leadsto higher land-related investment but that, with less than a third ofhouseholds — normally the better off — being well-in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med, ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tsto disseminate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> could signifi cantly impact productivity andequity (Deininger et al. 2006.)184 Eighty-nine neighbourhoods were upgraded or created under theprogram in Ceara, Brazil, to the benefi t of 25,300 families (more than100,000 people) using an intergovernmental/community partnership ofself-help housing, whereby the state fi nanced infrastructure and housingmaterials, the municipality furnished the land and the benefi ciariesc<strong>on</strong>structed their own housing, with technical assistance. 100,000people got access to housing and property rights. Importantly, theseinvestments were achieved with a per-family investment of US$2,100,including project, works, land and social mobilisati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main less<strong>on</strong>sfrom this programme are that Government programmes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> housing canbecome a mechanism <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> property rights creati<strong>on</strong> or regularizati<strong>on</strong>, raisingstr<strong>on</strong>g incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> communities’ c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the upgrade ofliving c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s through investments in services and houses c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>.(Ceara, Brazil: Urban Development and Water Resources ManagementProject).185 In the 1960s, Singapore faced a serious problem of housingshortage. In resp<strong>on</strong>se, the government set clear targets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> housingprovisi<strong>on</strong> and reorganised the housing industry. It passed the Housingand Development ordinance in 1960 which created the Housing andDevelopment Board (HDB) with a str<strong>on</strong>g mandate and resources to deliverhousing units. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fi rst priority of the agency was to build as manylow-cost housing units as quickly as possible. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> housing that wasinitially built was largely <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rental by low-income groups. Forty years<strong>on</strong>, approximately 85 percent of Singapore’s 3.4m resident populati<strong>on</strong> iscurrently living in HDB housing. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> majority of these people own theirhomes. In 1964 the government introduced the Home Ownership <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thePeople scheme to help all citizens to buy homes up to their capabilityas c<strong>on</strong>sumers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> aim is to give citizens including the poor an assetin the country. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> lowest income citizens are not excluded from thehousing system. This has encouraged the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong> of policies aimedat reducing the cost of housing and easing access to owner occupati<strong>on</strong>in public housing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all including the lower income residents. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>c<strong>on</strong>sequence of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal housing titles is increased housing investment,a greater sense of stakeholding and interest in the maintenance, qualityand design of the public housing. After more than 4 decades of publichousing development, an increasing number of people have pers<strong>on</strong>allychosen high-rise living and 82.5 percent of households in public housinghave expressed c<strong>on</strong>tentment at the idea of always living in publichousing fl ats.186 World Bank 2003a.187 For the most part of the following passages see Martinez 2007.188 Satterthwaite 2005.189 McKe<strong>on</strong> 1962; Harris 2004; Krieger and Higgins 2002; V<strong>on</strong> Hoffman1998.190 Since 1984, Grameen Bank is giving housing loans, the maximumbeing fi xed at Tk 15,000 (US$217) at an interest rate of 8 percent. It isto be repaid over a period of 5 years in weekly installments. 644,965houses have been c<strong>on</strong>structed with the housing loans averaging Tk13,194 (US$191). A total amount of Tk 8.51 billi<strong>on</strong> (US$203.98 milli<strong>on</strong>)has been disbursed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> housing loans. During the past 12 m<strong>on</strong>ths (fromApril’06 to March’07) 13,590 houses have been built with housing loansamounting to Tk 143.86 milli<strong>on</strong> (US$2.07 milli<strong>on</strong>) (Grameen Bank).191 Buckley and Kalarichal 2006.192 For Eastern European countries see Palacin and Shelbourne,2005: 7. Struyk and Turner, 1986, the study of South Korea and thePhilippines, noted that occupants with <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector titles, across allincome categories, enjoyed better quality housing in both countries.120


193 See Tomlins<strong>on</strong> 2007.194 UN-ESCAP 1994; Banerjee, 1995. Haryana Urban DevelopmentAuthority (HUDA) in India enters into partnership with private developersto develop townships in the highly sought-after periphery of Delhi. Thisland is under agricultural land ceiling and not available <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> urban use,except with the permissi<strong>on</strong> of HUDA with the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> that 20 percentof the housing should go to the poor.195 TDR is included as part of the nati<strong>on</strong>al urban policy in Brazil.Implementati<strong>on</strong> started with 10,000 houses <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 120 co-operatives ofthe poor between 1989 and 1992 in Sao Paolo. (Fernandes, 2002.) NGOslike Instituto Polis c<strong>on</strong>tinue to provide advocacy and technical and legalassistance to slum communities and land owners to implement theapproach in several cities of Brazil. In Mumbai TDR is linked with thegovernment’s policy of 1999 of providing houses free of cost to 4 milli<strong>on</strong>slum dwellers in fi ve years. (Burra, 2005.)196 UN-ESCAP, 1994.197 See Panaritis, 2007.198 Guidance can be found in Alden Wily 2002. See also Deininger etal. 2007; see ILD 1994, 2002, 2004.199 Mosqueira, 2007.200 See Collier 2007: 135-140.201 Rajan, 2005.202 Collier 2007: 140-156.Chapter 2 BibliographyAcemoglu, D. and J.A. Robins<strong>on</strong>. 2005. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Origins of Democracyand Dictatorships. Cambridge University Press.Acemoglu, Dar<strong>on</strong>, James Robins<strong>on</strong> and Sim<strong>on</strong> Johns<strong>on</strong>. 2004. ‘Instituti<strong>on</strong>sas the Fundamental Cause of L<strong>on</strong>g-Run Growth.’NBER <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper No. 10481.ADB. 2002. Indigenous Peoples/Ethnic Minorities and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>:Philippines. Manila: Asian Development Bank.Agarwal, Bina. 1994. A Field of One’s Own. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.Ahmed, Fauzia Erfan. 2007. ‘Microcredit, Segmentati<strong>on</strong>, and PovertyAlleviati<strong>on</strong> Strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Women.’ In: Kasturi Rangan et al.:15-24Alden Wily, Liz and Mbaya, S. 2001. Land, people and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests in easternand southern Africa at the beginning of the 21st Century.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact of land relati<strong>on</strong>s of the role of communities in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>est future. IUCN-EARO.Alden Wily, Liz. 2002. Getting the Process Right: Land Administrati<strong>on</strong>as Governance: A discourse <strong>on</strong> the political ec<strong>on</strong>omy ofland tenure management. Comments <strong>on</strong> the <strong>Legal</strong> Basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Land Administrati<strong>on</strong> in an African C<strong>on</strong>text. Paper presentedto the World Bank Land Policy C<strong>on</strong>ference in Africa, April29-May 2 2002, Kampala, Uganda._______. 2003. Governance and Land Relati<strong>on</strong>s. A Review of Decentralizati<strong>on</strong>of Land Administrati<strong>on</strong> and Management inAfrica. Land Tenure and Resources Series. Internati<strong>on</strong>alInstitute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Development [IIED] L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>._______. 2004a. Putting Rural Land Registrati<strong>on</strong> in Perspective:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Afghanistan Case in Proceedings Land Administrati<strong>on</strong>in Post C<strong>on</strong>fl ict Areas; 71-93. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Federati<strong>on</strong> ofSurveyors <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> 7 Cadastre and Land Management,2004. http://www.fi g.net/commissi<strong>on</strong>7/geneva_2004/index.htm (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> original draft <strong>on</strong>ly)_______. 2004b. Rural Land Relati<strong>on</strong>s in C<strong>on</strong>fl ict: A Way Forward.Policy Brief. Afghanistan Research and Evaluati<strong>on</strong> Unit,Kabul August 2004. http://www.areu.org.af_______. 2005. From Meeting Needs to H<strong>on</strong>ouring Rights: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Evoluti<strong>on</strong>of Community Forestry Chapter 19 in <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> EarthscanReader in Forestry and Development (ed. Jeffrey Sayer)2005; 388-394. Earthscan UK (originally a Keynote Addressto the World Forestry C<strong>on</strong>gress Quebec 2003)_______. 2006. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Comm<strong>on</strong>s and Customary <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Modern Times:Rethinking the Orthodoxies. In From Knowledge to Acti<strong>on</strong>. EMwangi (ed.). CaPri, Washingt<strong>on</strong>._______. 2006b. Formalizing the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal: Is <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re a Way to SecureHuman Potential through Land Entitlement? A Review ofChanging Administrati<strong>on</strong> in Africa, in: Linking the Formaland In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy C<strong>on</strong>cepts and Policies. Edited by B.Guha-khasnobis, R. Kunbur and E. Ostrom. Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d UniversityPress._______. 2006c. Land Rights Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and Governance in Africa: Howto Make it <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the 21st Century? UNDP October 2006.______. 2007. An Interim Note <strong>on</strong> Customary Land Tenure in Post-C<strong>on</strong>fl ict Liberia.121


Alexander, E. 2001. ‘A Transacti<strong>on</strong> Costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory of Land Use Planningand Development C<strong>on</strong>trol,’ Town Planning Review 72/1:45-76.Allanic, Benoît. 2003. «La nouvelle coutume urbaine: Évoluti<strong>on</strong>comparée des fi lières coutumières de la gesti<strong>on</strong> f<strong>on</strong>cièreurbaine dans les pays d’Afrique subSaharienne. Le cas deMandela Village, South Africa. » ISTED, DFID.Alst<strong>on</strong>, Lee, Gary Libecap and Robert Schneider. 1996. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Determinantsand Impact of Property Rights: Land Titles <strong>on</strong> theBrazilian Fr<strong>on</strong>tier.’ Journal of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, and Organisati<strong>on</strong>12:1 (1996): 1569-1614.Aristazabal, Nora and Andres Gomes.2004. ‘Improving Security withoutTitles in Bogotá.’ Habitat Internati<strong>on</strong>al 28/2.Asian Development Bank. 2004. Technical Assistance to the IslamicRepublic of Afghanistan <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Capacity Building in LandPolicy and Administrati<strong>on</strong> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. Manila: ADB.Augustinus, Clarissa and Barry, Michael. 2006. ‘Land ManagementStrategy Formulati<strong>on</strong> in Post C<strong>on</strong>fl ict Societies.’ SurveyReview 38: 668-681.Augustinus, Clarissa. 2003. ‘Handbook <strong>on</strong> Best Practices: Securityof Tenure and Access to Land — Implementati<strong>on</strong> of theHabitat Agenda.’ UN-Habitat, Nairobi.Baechtold, Philippe. 2006. ‘Public Policy Objectives and IntellectualProperty Rights.’ In: de Soto/Cheneval 2006: 266-277.Banerjee, Abhijit and Lakshmi. Iyer. 2005. ‘History, Instituti<strong>on</strong>s andEc<strong>on</strong>omic Per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Legacy of Col<strong>on</strong>ial Land TenureSystems in India.’ Available at: http://ec<strong>on</strong>-www.mit.edu/fi les/511Banerjee, Banashree. 2002. ‘Security of Tenure in Indian Cities.’ In:Durand-Lasserve, A. and Royst<strong>on</strong> L. (eds.). Holding theirGround: Secure Land Tenure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Urban in DevelopingCountries, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Earthscan Publicati<strong>on</strong>s, 37-58._______. 2004. ‘Maximising the impact of tenure and infrastructureprogrammes <strong>on</strong> housing c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s: the case of slums inIndian Cities’ paper presented at Internati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>ference<strong>on</strong> Adequate and Af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable Housing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> All - Research,Policy, Practice, June 24-27, Tor<strong>on</strong>to_______. 2005. ‘Recogniti<strong>on</strong>, Regularizati<strong>on</strong> and Relocati<strong>on</strong> of Slumsin Madhya Pradesh.’ Background Note <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the design ofDFID supported Madhya Pradesh Urban Services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thePoor (Mimeo)_______. 2006. ‘Land Titling in Urban and Peri-urban Areas in India:Experiences and Issues.’ Paper presented at the Research<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>shop <strong>on</strong> Social and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Impacts of Land titlingin Urban and Peri-urban Areas, Charney Manor, CharneyBassett, UK, 12-15 December 2006._______. 1995. ‘Urban Land: Is there hope <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor?’ In: Singh,K. and Steinberg, F. (eds.), Urban India in Crisis, Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d,New Delhi.Barry, Michael. 2002. Periurban Agriculture and Tenure in South Africa:Strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tenure Regularizati<strong>on</strong>. United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Foodand Agricultural Organisati<strong>on</strong> (FAO) publicati<strong>on</strong> series,Rome.Barzel, Y. 1997. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge, MA:Cambridge University Press.Benjaminsen, T. A. 2006. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> emerging <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> agenda andsome empirical evidence from Africa.’A paper presented atthe Colloque internati<strong>on</strong>al: At the Fr<strong>on</strong>tier of Land Issues.Social Embeddedness of rights and public policy. M<strong>on</strong>tpellierCampus ENSAM-INRA, France, May 17, 18 and19 2006.Bertaud A. and Malpezzi S. 2001. ‘Measuring the Costs and Benefi ts ofUrban Land Use Regulati<strong>on</strong>: A Simple Model with an Applicati<strong>on</strong>to Malaysia,’ Journal of Housing Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 10/3:393-418.Besley, Timothy. 1995. ‘Property Rights and Investment Incentives:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory and Evidence from Ghana,’ Journal of PoliticalEc<strong>on</strong>omy 103(5), 903-937.Binswanger, Hans, Klaus Deininger and Gersh<strong>on</strong> Feder. 1995. ‘Power,Distorti<strong>on</strong>s, Revolt, and Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in Agrarian Relati<strong>on</strong>s.’ InJ. Berman and T.N. Srinivasan (eds.). Handbook of DevelopmentEc<strong>on</strong>omics. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, NorthHolland.Bird, M. and E. Slack. 2002. ‘Land and Property Taxati<strong>on</strong> around theWorld: A Review 2002.’ Paper presented in Hungary andMexico at World Bank Policy SeminarsBlesoe, David. 2006. ‘Can Land Titling and Registrati<strong>on</strong> Reduce Poverty?’In Bruce et al. 2006: 143-174.Bo<strong>on</strong>yabancha, Somsook. 2005. ‘Mainstreaming community led processes<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> housing and poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong>: the developmentof CODI and the Baan Mank<strong>on</strong>g Programme.’ Case Study21 — Thailand, available at http://www.community-planning.netBoudreaux, Karol. 2007. ‘State Power, Entrepreneurship, and Coffee:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rwandan Experience.’ Mercatus Centre. EnterpriseAfrica! <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper_______. 2006. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effects of Property Titling in Langa Township,South Africa.’ Mercatus Policy Series, Policy Comment No.4, available at: http://www.enterprise-africa.org/repository/docLib/20060524_Langa.pdf_______. 2007. ‘Community-Based Natural Resource Managementand Poverty Alleviati<strong>on</strong> in Namibia: A Case Study.’ MercatusPolicy Series, Policy Comment Nr. 10.Bruce, John W. and Migot-Adholla, S. (eds.). 1994. Searching <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Securityof Land Tenure in Africa. Dubuque, IA: Kendall/Hunt.Bruce, John W. 2006. ‘Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of Land <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the C<strong>on</strong>text of World BankLending.’ in Bruce et al. 2006, pp. 11-65.Bruce, John W., Giovarelli, R. Giovarelli, L. Rolfes, D. Bledsoe and R.Mitchell. 2006. Land <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. Achieving DevelopmentPolicy Objectives. World Bank <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Justice, and DevelopmentSeries. Washingt<strong>on</strong>: WB.Brustinow, Angelika. 2006. ‘Out of Court Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong> as aPractical Tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment”, in: NorwegianMinistry of Foreign Affairs, <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment, issue 2,Oslo: 91-113.Buckley, Robert M. and Jerry Kalarickal. 2006. ‘Land Market Issues:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Mystery of Capital Revisited. Urban Land Policy — IsTitling the Answer?’ in Buckley and Kalarickal (eds.). Thirtyyears of World Bank Shelter Lending: Directi<strong>on</strong>s in DevelopmentInfrastructure. World Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.Burns, T<strong>on</strong>y. 2006. ‘Internati<strong>on</strong>al Experience with Land Administrati<strong>on</strong>Projects: a Framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> M<strong>on</strong>itoring of Pilots’. Paper122


presented at the Nati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>shop <strong>on</strong> Land Policies andAdministrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Accelerated Growth and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>in the 21st Century (Jan 5-6) New Delhi.Burra, Sundar. 2005. Towards a Pro-Poor Framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Slum-Upgradingin Mumbai, India,’ Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Urbanisati<strong>on</strong>,17/1.Calder n Cockburn, Julio. 2004. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of property in Peru2001-2002: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> case of Lima,’ Habitat Internati<strong>on</strong>al 28:289-300Cantuarias, Fernando and Delgado, Miguel. 2004. ‘Peru’s urban landtitling program’ Case study from ‘Reducing poverty, sustaininggrowth — what works, what doesn’t and why? Aglobal exchange <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> scaling up success.’ Shanghai, May25-27, World BankCarter, Michael and Pedro Olinto. 2003. ‘Getting Instituti<strong>on</strong>s ‘Right’<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Whom? Credit C<strong>on</strong>straints and the Impact of PropertyRights <strong>on</strong> the Quantity and Compositi<strong>on</strong> of Investment,’American Journal of Agricultural Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 85/1: 173-186.Cavallar, Georg. 2002. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rights of Strangers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ories of Internati<strong>on</strong>alHospitality, the Global Community, and Political Justicesince Vitoria. Aldershot.Ceara, Brasil: Urban Development and Water Resources ManagementProject).Center <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Advanced Study, in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with the Ministry of LandManagement, Urban Planning and C<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> — Nati<strong>on</strong>alCadastral <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> Secretariat, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank— Justice <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor Program, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> German DevelopmentCooperati<strong>on</strong> (GTZ). 2007. ‘Towards Instituti<strong>on</strong>alJustice? A Review of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> of Cambodia’s Cadastral<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> in Relati<strong>on</strong> to Land Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong>’ (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>thcoming)Chanell, Wade. 2006. ‘Bringing More Dead Capital to Life’. RAFiNotes (Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: US AID).Cheneval, Francis. 2006. ‘Property Rights as Human Rights’, in: deSoto and Cheneval 2006: 11-17.Chi<strong>on</strong>g-Javier, M. E. 1989. ‘Ownership and Property Rights Issues inWatershed Resource Management.’ Journal of PhilippineDevelopment 26/1: 101-113.Ch<strong>on</strong>g, A. and M. Gradstein. 2007a. ‘Inequality and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality’, availableat: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=910215Ch<strong>on</strong>g, A. and M. Gradstein. 2007b. ‘Inequality and Instituti<strong>on</strong>s.’Review of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Statistics, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>thcoming.COHRE. 2000. ‘Women and Housing Rights,’ Geneva, Switzerland:COHRE.Colchester, Marcus/Mackay, Fergus/Griffi ths, Tom and Nels<strong>on</strong>, J<strong>on</strong>.2001. ‘A Survey of Indigenous Land Tenure’. Forest PeoplesProgramme, REF: RA 42/1, PE ç/173.Collier, Paul and J.W. Gunning. 1999. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Microec<strong>on</strong>omics of AfricanGrowth, 1950-2000.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>matic Paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the AERC CollaborativeResearch Project <strong>on</strong> ‘Explaining African Ec<strong>on</strong>omicGrowth, 1950-2000.’Collier, Paul. 2007. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Bottom Billi<strong>on</strong>. Why the Poorest Countries AreFailing and What Can be D<strong>on</strong>e about it. Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d: Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dUniversity Press.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor (CLEP), Nati<strong>on</strong>alC<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> Report, Property Rights, Ind<strong>on</strong>esiaCLEP, Nati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> Report, In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses, India______. Property Rights, Kenya______. Property Rights, Pakistan______. Property Rights, Philippines: Mendoza, Amado M. 2006.‘Property Rights and the Empowerment of the Poor in thePhilippines’.______. South America Report______. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Land Market, Sri Lanka______. Property Rights, Tanzania: Kir<strong>on</strong>de, Lusugga. 2006. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g>Property Rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor in Tanzania’.______. Property Rights, Uganda.______. Grassroots Academy, Property Secti<strong>on</strong>.C<strong>on</strong>gress <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the NewUrbanism. 1999. Charter of the New Urbanism, New York,McGraw Hill.C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Biological Diversity (CBD) of June 5, 1992, , at: http://www.wipo.int/freepublicati<strong>on</strong>s/en/tk/920/wipo_pub_920.pdfCotula, Lorenzo (ed). 2007. Changes in ‘Customary’ Land Tenure Systemsin Africa. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>/Rome: iied/FAO.Coudouel, Aline/Dani, Anis A./Paternostro, Stefano. 2007. SocialImpact Analysis of Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Less<strong>on</strong>s and Examples fromImplementati<strong>on</strong>. Washingt<strong>on</strong>: IBRD/WB.Currey, James. 2004. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Federati<strong>on</strong> of Surveyors, 2004, LandAdministrati<strong>on</strong> in Post C<strong>on</strong>fl ict Areas. Proceedings of aSymposium held by FIG <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> 7, Geneva, April 2004.Dabla-Norris, E., Gradstein, M., and G. Inchauste. 2007. Journal ofDevelopment Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>thcoming.David, Cristina, et al. 2003. ‘Land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and land market transacti<strong>on</strong>sin the Philippines.’ Terminal Report. Philippine Institute<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development Studies.De Soto, Hernando. 2006. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Challenge of C<strong>on</strong>necting In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal andFormal Property Systems’, in: De Soto/Cheneval 2006, pp.18-67._______. 2000. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs inthe West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books._______. 1989. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Other Path. New York: Basic BooksDe Soto, Hernando and Cheneval, Francis (eds.). 2006. RealisingProperty Rights, Zurich: RüfferandRub.Deere, Carmen Diana and Magdalena Le<strong>on</strong>. 2003. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Gender AssetGap: Land in Latin America,’ World Development 31(6:925-947.Deininger K. 2003. ‘Land Policies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Growth and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>’, AWorld Bank Policy Research Report, Washingt<strong>on</strong> DCDeininger, K. and Jin, S. 2003. ‘Land Sales and Rental Markets inTransiti<strong>on</strong> — Evidence from Rural Vietnam,’ WPS 3013,available at: http://ec<strong>on</strong>.worldbank.orgDeininger, K., Alayew, D. and Yamano T. 2006. <strong>Legal</strong> Knowledge andEc<strong>on</strong>omic Development: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case of Land Rights in Uganda.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank.Deininger, K. and J. Chamorro. 2004. ‘Investment and Equity Effects ofLand Regularizati<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case of Nicaragua,’ AgriculturalEc<strong>on</strong>omics 30/2: 101-116.123


Deininger, Klaus and Squire, Lyn. 1998. ‘New Ways of Looking at OldIssues: Inequality and Growth,’ Journal of DevelopmentEc<strong>on</strong>omics 57: 259-287.Deininger, Klaus, Ayalew, Daniel and Alemu, Tekie. 2006. ‘Land Rentalin Ethiopia. Marshallian Ineffi ciency or Factor Market Imperfecti<strong>on</strong>sand Tenure Insecurity as Binding C<strong>on</strong>straints?’available at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/RPDL-PROGRAM/Resources/459596-1161903702549/S4_Ali.ppt#311,27,Folie 27Deininger, Klaus/ Ayalew, Daniel/ Holden, Stein/Zeevenbergen, Jaap.2007. ‘Rural Land Certifi cati<strong>on</strong> in Ethiopia. Process, InitialImpact, and Implicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Other African Countries,’World Bank Policy Research <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper WPS 4218.Deininger, Klaus/Jin, S<strong>on</strong>gquing/Nagarajan, Hari K. 2007b. ‘Determinantsand C<strong>on</strong>sequences of Land Sales Market Participati<strong>on</strong>:Panel Evidence from India,’ World Bank PolicyResearch <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper WPS 4323.Deng, Y<strong>on</strong>gheng, Della Zheng and Changfeng Ling. 2005. ‘An Early Assessmentof Residential Mortgage Per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance in China,’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Journal of Real Estate Finance and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 31/2.Di Gregorio, M., K. Hagedorn, M. Kirk, B. Korf, N. McCarty, and R. Meinzin-Dick.2005. ‘A Framework <strong>on</strong> Instuti<strong>on</strong>al Change <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Resource Management and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role ofProperty Rights and Collective Acti<strong>on</strong>.’ Paper presented atthe 99th seminar of the European Associati<strong>on</strong> of AgriculturalEc<strong>on</strong>omists, Copenhagen, August 24-27, 2005.Diop, Maleye. 2007. ‘An example of an innovative participatory slumupgrading and land regularizati<strong>on</strong> initiative <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor inSenegal,’ C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to CLEP working group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chapter2, <strong>on</strong> Property Rights.Du Plessis, Jean. 2005. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Growing Problem of Forced Evicti<strong>on</strong>sand the Crucial Importance of Community-Based, LocallyAppropriate Alternatives,’ Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Urbanizati<strong>on</strong>17/1: 123-134.Durand-Lasserve A. 2003. Land Issues and Security of Tenure. BackgroundReport prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the UN Millenium Project TaskForce <strong>on</strong> Improving the Lives of Slum Dwellers. Nati<strong>on</strong>alCentre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Scientifi c Research, France.______. 2006. ‘Market-driven evicti<strong>on</strong>s and displacements: Implicati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the perpetuati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements in developingcities.’ In: Huchzermeyer, M., and Karam, A. (Editors).In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements. A perpetual challenge? University ofCape Town Press.Durand-Lasserve, A. and G. Payne. 2006. ‘Evaluating Impacts of UrbanLand Titling: Results and Implicati<strong>on</strong>s: Preliminary Findings.’(Ms.)Ec<strong>on</strong>omist . 2006. ‘Property and Poverty’, August 24.European <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>. 2007. Joint Report <strong>on</strong> Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> andSocial Inclusi<strong>on</strong>Food and Agricultural Organisati<strong>on</strong> (FAO). 2002. Land administrati<strong>on</strong>and rural development. Rome______. 2005. State of the World’s Forests, Rome______. 2006. ‘Reclaiming our lives: HIV and AIDS, women’s landand property rights, and livelihoods in southern and EastAfrica,’ Cape Town, South Africa: HSRC Press.______. 2007. Good governance in land tenure and administrati<strong>on</strong>.Rome.Feder, G. and A. Nishio. 1996. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Benefi ts of Land Registrati<strong>on</strong> andTitling: Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Social Perspectives,’ Land Use Policy15(1): 25-43.Feder, G./Onchan, T./Raparla, T. 1988. Collateral, guarantees and ruralcredit in developing countries: Evidence from Asia. AgriculturalEc<strong>on</strong>omics 2: 231-245.Fernandes E. 2002. ‘Combining Tenure Policies, Urban Planning andCity Management in Brazil.’ In: Payne, Geoffrey (ed.). Land,Rights and Innovati<strong>on</strong> - Improving Tenure Security <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theUrban Poor, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: ITDG.______. 2006. ‘Principles, Bases and Challenges of the Nati<strong>on</strong>alProgramme to Support Sustainable Urban Land Regularizati<strong>on</strong>in Brazil.’ In: Huchzermeyer, M. and Karam, A. (eds.)In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements. A perpetual challenge? University ofCape Town Press, p. 62-83.Field, Erica. 2004. ‘Property rights, community public goods, andhousehold time allocati<strong>on</strong> in urban squatter communities:Evidence from Peru.’ William and Mary <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review 45(3):838—887.______.2005. ‘Property rights and investment in urban slums.’ Journalof European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Associati<strong>on</strong>, April-May 3 (2-3):279-290.Firmin-Sellers, K. and Sellers, P. 1999. ‘Expected failures and unexpectedsuccesses of land titling in Africa,’ World Development27/7: 1115-1999.Food and Agricultural Organisati<strong>on</strong> (FAO). 1999. Women’s right to landand natural resources: some implicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a humanrightsbased approach. SD Dimensi<strong>on</strong>s, at: http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LTan0025.htm).Galiani, S. and E. Schargrodsky. 2004. ‘Property Rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thePoor: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect of Land Titling,’ At: http://200.32.4.58/~eschargr/______. 2004a. ‘Effects of land titling <strong>on</strong> child health,’ Ec<strong>on</strong>omicsand Human Biology 2: 353-372.Garcia-Bolivar, Omar. 2007. ‘A Broader Defi niti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor’. Paper presented to the ANLEP workshop,Oslo Oct. 25-26, 2007 (mimeo).Giovarelli, Renée, Susana Lastarria-Cornhiel, Elizabeth Katz, and SueNichols. 2005. Gender Issues and Best Practices in LandAdministrati<strong>on</strong> Projects: A Synthesis Report. Agricultureand Rural Development Department. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank.Report No. 32571-GLB. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank.Glend<strong>on</strong>, Mary Ann. 2001. A World Made New. Eleanor Roosevelt andthe Universal Declarati<strong>on</strong> of Human Rights. New York:Randam House.Golub, S. 2003. ‘Bey<strong>on</strong>d the Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Orthodoxy: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> EmpowermentAlternative.’ Carnegie Endowment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>alPeace (CEIP) <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper No. 41.Government of India. 1998. Nati<strong>on</strong>al Housing and Habitat Policy, NewDelhi, Ministry of Urban Development._______. 2004. Nati<strong>on</strong>al Policy <strong>on</strong> Urban Street Vendors, New Delhi,Ministry of Urban Employment and Poverty Alleviati<strong>on</strong>.Gradstein, Mark. 2006. ‘Inequality, Democracy, and the Protecti<strong>on</strong> of124


Property Rights.’ At: http://www.iew.unizh.ch/study/courses/downloads/markgradstein.pdfGROOTS Kenya. 2006. A Final Report <strong>on</strong> Grassroots Community InputTo the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor— Hearing in Kenya, at: http://www.undp.org/legalempowerment/pdf/Microsoft%20Word%20-%20GROOTS%20Kenya%20Final%20Report%20_2_.pdfGuyers, Steven. 2005. ‘You’d be surprised what can be used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>collateral,’ Denver Business Journal. Available at: http://www.bizjournals.com/denver/stories/2005/06/06/smallb6.htmlHaldrup, K. 2003. ‘From elitist standards to basic needs — diversifi edstrategies to land registrati<strong>on</strong> serving poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong>objectives’. Presented at 2nd FIG Regi<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>ference,Marrakech, Morocco December 2-5, 2003.Handbook <strong>on</strong> Housing and Property Restituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Refugees andDisplaced Pers<strong>on</strong>s. Implementing the ‘Pinheiro Principles’(OCHA/IDD, UN HABITAT, UNHCR, FAO, OHCHR, NRC, IDMC2007).Hardin, Garret. 1968. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tragedy of the Comm<strong>on</strong>s,’ Science,162/3859: 1243-1248Hart, H.L.A. 1961. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>cept of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d: Clarend<strong>on</strong> Press.Heller, Michael A. 1998. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tragedy of the Anticomm<strong>on</strong>s: Property inthe Transiti<strong>on</strong> from Marx to Markets’, Harvard <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review111: 621-688.Hodgs<strong>on</strong>, Stephen. 2004. ‘Land and Water — <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rights Interface.’FAO, LSP <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper 10. Access to Natural ResourcesSub-Programme.Hunt, Diana. 2004. ‘Unintended C<strong>on</strong>sequences of Land Rights Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case of the 1998 Uganda Land Act’ Development PolicyReview 22/2: 173-191.Hurwitz, A./Studdard, K./Williams, R. 2005. ‘Housing, Land, Propertyand C<strong>on</strong>fl ict Management: Identifying Policy Opti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Programming,’ Policy Paper. Internati<strong>on</strong>alPeace Academy. FAO 2005. Access to rural land and landadministrati<strong>on</strong> after violent c<strong>on</strong>fl icts, FAO Land TenureStudies 8, Rome.Instituto Libertad y Democracia (ILD). 1994. ILD Estimates. Annex 1:Some of the ILD’s Practical Achievements and Annex 3:Business Formalizati<strong>on</strong>. Available at: http://www.ild.org.pe/pdf/annex/Annex_01.pdf and http://www.ild.org.pe/pdf/annex/Annex_03.pdf______. 2002. Supporting workers in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: A PolicyFramework.______. 2004. ‘Dead Capital in Egypt.’ Available at: http://www.ild.org.pe/pdf/posters/egypt_en.pdf.______. 2005. Program to Formalize the Assets of the Poor in Tanzaniaand Strengthen the Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Six Volumes. Dar esSalaam: ILD.Inter-American Development Bank (IADB). 2005. Unlocking Credit.Available at: http://idbdocs.iadb.org/wsdocs/getdocument.aspx?docnum=617000______. ‘Access to Financing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Small and Medium Enterprises’ In:Unlocking Credit, 2005 Report, available at: http://www.iadb.org/res/ipes/2005/docs/Chapter14Eng.pdfInter-Ministerial <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Group. 2004. Afghanistan: Land Policy and itsImplementati<strong>on</strong>. www.icarrd.org/en/icard_doc_down/nati<strong>on</strong>al_Afghanistan.doc.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Center <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Research <strong>on</strong> Women (ICRW). 2005. ‘PropertyOwnership <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Women Enriches, Empowers and Protects:Toward Achieving the Third Millennium Development Goalto Promote Gender Equality and Empower Women,’ Washingt<strong>on</strong>,DCInternati<strong>on</strong>al Fund <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agricultural Development (IFAD). 2001. RuralPoverty Report, 2001. Available at: http://www.ifad.org/poverty/index.htmInternati<strong>on</strong>al Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Development (IIED). 2006.‘Local Innovati<strong>on</strong> in Securing Land Rights in Africa: Less<strong>on</strong>sfrom experience,’ Briefi ng Paper, IIED, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>Inter-Summit Property System Initiative. 2006. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Inter-SummitProperty Systems Initiative (IPSI)’ Summary Presentati<strong>on</strong>.Broad-based Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth Team Regi<strong>on</strong>al SustainableDevelopment Bureau <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Latin America and the CaribbeanUSAID Washingt<strong>on</strong>.Izumi, Kaori. 2007. ‘Gender-Based Violence and Property Grabbing inAfrica: A denial of Women’s Liberty and Security,’ Genderand Development 15(1): 11-23.Jacobs, J. 1961. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Death and Life of Great American Cities, NewYork: Vintage.Jacoby, Hanan and Minten, Bart. 2005. ‘Is Land Titling In Sub-Saharan Africa Cost-Effective. Evidence from Madagascar’,available at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTISPMA/Resources/Training-Events-and-Materials/Land_Titles_MG.pdfKaelin, Walter. 2006. ‘Internal Displacement and the Protecti<strong>on</strong> ofProperty,’ in: de Soto/Cheneval 2006: 175-185.Kasturi Rangan, V./Quelch, J.A./Herrero, G./Bart<strong>on</strong>, B. 2007. BusinessSoluti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Global Poor. San Francisco: Wiley andS<strong>on</strong>s.Keefer, Philip and Knack, Stephen. 2002. ‘Polarizati<strong>on</strong>, Politics andProperty Rights: Links between inequality and Growth,’Public Choice 111: 127-154.Krant<strong>on</strong>, Rachel E. and Anand V. Swamy. 1999. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Hazards of PiecemealRe<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m: British Courts and the Credit Market in Col<strong>on</strong>ialIndia,’ Journal of Development Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 58: 1-24.Krieger, James and Higgins, D<strong>on</strong>na L. 2002. ‘Housing and Health: TimeAgain <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Health Acti<strong>on</strong>,’ American Journal of PublicHealth 92/5: 758-768.Land Administrati<strong>on</strong> and Management Project (LAMP) 2, Departmentof Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Natural Resources. ‘Frequently askedquesti<strong>on</strong>s.’ Available at: www.phil-lamp.org/faq.htmlLand Tenure Lexic<strong>on</strong>. 2000. A glossary of terms from English andFrench speaking West Africa. Compiled by Rebeca Le<strong>on</strong>ardand Judy L<strong>on</strong>gbottom. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>, available at: http://www.landcoaliti<strong>on</strong>.org/pdf/07_lexic<strong>on</strong>_FS_ied.pdfLobo, A. and Balakrishnan, S. 2002. Report <strong>on</strong> Service of BhoomiKiosks: An Assessment of Benefi ts by Users of the ComputerisedLand Records System in Karnataka. Bangalore:Public Affairs Centre.Locke, John. 1988 [1689]. Sec<strong>on</strong>d Treatise of Government. New York:125


Cambridge University Press. -- An argument <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the right toproperty, based <strong>on</strong> our property in ourselves.LTC/Land Tenure Center. 2002. ‘Assessment of USAID investmentsin land markets and property rights: Synthesis based <strong>on</strong>USAID documentati<strong>on</strong>’ Land Tenure Center, University ofWisc<strong>on</strong>sin, September______. 2002. ‘Guidelines <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Analysis of USAID’s Land MarketProjects’ Documents Annex 3 Assessment Guidelines,University of Wisc<strong>on</strong>sin______. 2002a. ‘An assessment of USAID’s investments in land marketsand property rights in Albania: documentary evidence’,Land Tenure Center, University of Wisc<strong>on</strong>sin, SeptemberMacours, Karen/de Janvry, Alain/Sadoulet, Elisabeth.2004. ‘Insecurityof Property Rights and Matching in the Tenancy Market,’Department of Agricultural and Resource Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, UCB.CUDARE <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper 992. http://repositories.cdlib.org/are_ucb/992Martinez, Sylvia C. 2003. ‘Housing and Finance in Spain: A ComparativeStudy <strong>on</strong> Housing and Finance Principles.’ Unpublishedlecture delivered to Women in Housing and Finance, Jan.22, 2003. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.______. 2004. ‘Property Rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor a Global Perspective: ACase Study of Sites and Services in Mexicali, Baja Cali<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>nia.’Presentati<strong>on</strong> be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Ec<strong>on</strong>omic<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Europe Land Development Forum in Rome,Italy. December 13-14.______. 2007. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Settlements in Developing Countries: ARights-Based Approach to Land Policies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor’,Background Paper To <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Presentati<strong>on</strong> Be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> UnitedNati<strong>on</strong>s Ec<strong>on</strong>omic <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Europe <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Party <strong>on</strong>Land Administrati<strong>on</strong>, And Committee <strong>on</strong> Housing and LandManagement, And <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Federati<strong>on</strong> of Surveyors,28-31 March, Athens, Greece.______. 2007a.’Toward a Pro-poor Global Housing Partnership’.Research Study <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Harvard Joint Center <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> HousingStudies In Support of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor.McKeown, Thomas. R.G. Record. 1962. ‘Reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Decline of Mortalityin England and Wales during the Nineteenth Century,’Populati<strong>on</strong> Studies 16/2: 94-122.Merriam, Dwight. 2005. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Complete Guide to Z<strong>on</strong>ing. McGraw-Hill.Migot-Adholla, Shem E., George Benneh, Frank Place and Steven Atsu.1994. ‘Security of Tenure and Land Productivity in Kenya.’in Bruce and Migot-Adholla: 97-118.Mosqueira, Edgardo. 2007. ‘Urban Property Rights. Less<strong>on</strong>s and Impactsfrom WB Projects in LAC’ [draft].Nagarajan, G., C. David, and R. Meyer. 1992. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal FinanceThrough Land Pawning C<strong>on</strong>tracts: Evidence from the Philippines.’Journal of Development Studies 29(1): 93-107.Nagarajan, G., M. Quisumbing, and K. Otsuka. 1991. ‘Land pawningin the Philippines: an explorati<strong>on</strong> into the c<strong>on</strong>sequences ofland re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m regulati<strong>on</strong>s.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Developing Ec<strong>on</strong>omies 29/2:124-144.Nati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> Paper, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor (NCLEP), Ethiopia:Newman, Oscar. 1972. Defensible Space, New York: MacmillanNielsen, Robin. 2006. ‘If he asks me to leave this place, I will go’.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Challenge to Secure Equitable Land Rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> RuralWomen’, in: de Soto and Cheneval 2006: 204-219.Nugent, Jeffrey B. and Robins<strong>on</strong>, James A. 2002. ‘Are EndowmentsFate?’ Centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Policy Research Discussi<strong>on</strong>Paper No. 3206.Okoth-Ogendo H. W. O. .1999. Land policy development in East Africa:a survey of recent trends, a regi<strong>on</strong>al overview paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theDFID workshop <strong>on</strong> „land rights and sustainable developmentin Sub-Saharan Africa’, Sunningdale Park C<strong>on</strong>ferenceCentre, Berkshire, England, Great Britain, 16th-19 th February1999, at: http://www.oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/livelihoods/landrights/downloads/eafover.rtfOrganisati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Co-operati<strong>on</strong> and Development (OECD).2003. Land, Violent C<strong>on</strong>fl ict and Development. Paris: OCED.Padilla, S. 2007. ‘Indigenous Peoples, Settlers and the PhilippineAncestral Domain Land Titling program.’ (Forthcoming inFr<strong>on</strong>tier Encounters. University of Zurich Press).Palacin, José and Shelbourne, Robert C. 2005. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Private HousingMarket in Eastern Europe and the CIS,’ UNECE Discussi<strong>on</strong>Paper Series 6, DecemberPalmer, David. 1998. ‘Security, Risk and Registrati<strong>on</strong>,’ Land Use Policy15/1: 83-94Panaritis, Elena. 2007. Prosperity Unbound. Building Property Marketswith Trust. Forword by Francis Fukuyama. New York: PalgraveMacmillan.Payne, Geoffrey (ed.). 2002, ‘Land, Rights and Innovati<strong>on</strong>: Improvingtenure security <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the urban poor’ ITDG Publishing L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>______. 1997. ‘Urban Land Tenure and Property Rights in DevelopingCountries. A Review’, IT Publicati<strong>on</strong>s/ODA______. 2000. ‘Urban land tenure policy opti<strong>on</strong>s: titles or rights?’Paper presented at the World Bank Urban Forum, Westfi eldsMarriott, Virginia, USA 03-05 April, 2000______. 2005. ‘Getting ahead of the game: A twin-track approach toimproving existing slums and reducing the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> futureslums.’ Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> Vol 17 No 1, April,pp. 135-145.Pottier, Johan. 2005. ‘Land Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Peace? Rwanda’s 2005 Land<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> in C<strong>on</strong>text,’ Journal of Agrarian Change 6 (October2005).Prahalad, C.K. 2005. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid. EradicatingPoverty through Profi ts. Upper Saddle River: Whart<strong>on</strong>School Publishing.Prosterman, Roy. 2006. ‘Rural Property Right in China,’ in: de Soto/Cheneval 2006: 107-128.Quisumbing, A. and John Maluccio. 2000. ‘Intrahousehold Allocati<strong>on</strong>sand Gender Relati<strong>on</strong>s: New Empirical Evidence from FourDeveloping Countries,’ Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: IFRPR.Rajan, R.G. 2005. ‘Failed states, vicious cycles, and a proposal,’mimeo, http://faculty.chicagogsb.edu/raghuram.rajan/research/.Ravna, Øyvind. 2006. ‘Recogniti<strong>on</strong> of Indigenous People’s Land Rightsthrough Modern Legislati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case of the Sami Peoplein Norway’, in: Norwegian Ministry of Foreign Affairs, <strong>Legal</strong>126


Empowerment, issue 2, Oslo: 65-90.Richards, Paul. (ed.). 2005. No Peace, No War. An Anthropology ofC<strong>on</strong>temporary Armed C<strong>on</strong>fl icts. Ohio University Press.Rolfes, Le<strong>on</strong>ard. ‘A Framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Land Market <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> with the Poor inMind,’ in: Bruce et al. 2006: 107-142.Roll, Richard and Talbott, John. 2001. ‘Why Many Developing CountriesJust Aren’t,’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Anders<strong>on</strong> School at UCLA, Finance <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ingPaper No. 19-01, at:Sachs, Jeffrey. 2006. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> End of Poverty: Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Possibilities of ourTime. Penguin.Santiago, Astea. 2004. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and urban change in developing countries:the case of the Philippines.’ In: Fernandes, E. andVarley, A. (eds.) Illegal Cities: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Urban Change inDeveloping Countries, Zed Books, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>.Sattar, Sarosh and Shabih Mohib. 2007. ‘Tajikistan Cott<strong>on</strong> FarmlandPrivatizati<strong>on</strong>’, in: Coudouel et al. 2007: 453-488.Satterthwaite, David and D. Mitlin. 2004. Empowering Squatter Citizen.L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Development.Safavian, Mehnaz, Heywood Fleisig, and Jevgenijs Steinbuks. 2006.Unlocking Dead Capital. Viewpoint, Note No. 307 (Washingt<strong>on</strong>,DC: World Bank).Siddiqui, Tasneem and M. Azhar Khan. 1994. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Incremental DevelopmentScheme,’ Third World Planning Review 16/3:277-291.Singapore Housing and Development Board. Accessed at http://www.hdb.gov.sgSokoloff, K.L. and S.L. Engerman. 2000. ‘Instituti<strong>on</strong>s, factor endowments,and paths of development in the New World,’ Journalof Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Perspectives, 14, 217-232.South African Institute of Internati<strong>on</strong>al Affairs. 2005. Special Feature:Unleashing Investment By Encouraging African Savings, at:www.saiia.org.za/modules.php?op=modloadandname=Newsandfi le=articleandsid=648 [seen 13.6.07].SPARC. 1995. ‘We the invisible revisited.’ Available at: http://www.sparcindia.orgStanfi eld, David and Peter Bloch. 2002. ‘USAID investments in landmarkets and property rights: Interim assessment based<strong>on</strong> sec<strong>on</strong>dary sources’ Land Tenure Canter, University ofWisc<strong>on</strong>sin.Steuteville, Robert. 2005. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> New Urbanism: an alternative to modernautomobile-oriented planning and development, availableat: http://www.newurbanism.comStrickland, Richard S. 2004. ‘To Have and To Hold: Women’s Propertyand Inheritance Rights in the C<strong>on</strong>text of HIV/AIDS in Sub-Saharan Africa,’ Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: ICRW.Tibaijuka, Anna Kajumulo. 2005. Report of the Fact-Finding Missi<strong>on</strong>to Zimbabwe to assess the Scope and Impact of Operati<strong>on</strong>Murambatsvina by the UN Special Envoy <strong>on</strong> Human SettlementsIssues in Zimbabwe. July 18.Tomlins<strong>on</strong>, Mary R. 2007. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development of a Low-Income HousingFinance Sector in South Africa: Have We Finally Found aWay Forward,’ Habitat Internati<strong>on</strong>al 31.T<strong>on</strong>gs<strong>on</strong>, E. and McShane, T. 2004. ‘Securing Land Tenure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Biodiversity:C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> in Sibuyan Island, Rombl<strong>on</strong>, Philippines.”Paper presented at the UNU-WIDER and EGDIC<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> Unlocking Human Potential: Linking theIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and Formal Sectors, Helsinki, Finland.UN-ESCAP. 1994. Municipal Land Management in Asia: A comparativestudy, Bankok, UN-ESCAP.United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Human Settlements Programme (UN-Habitat). 2004.‘Guidelines <strong>on</strong> How to Undertake a Nati<strong>on</strong>al Campaign <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Secure Tenure,” UN-HABITAT website at: http://www.unhabitat.org/pmss/getPage.asp?page=bookViewandbook=1186.New York: UN-HABITAT.UN-Habitat. 2006. ‘Progress Report <strong>on</strong> Removing Discriminati<strong>on</strong>Against Women in Respect of Property and InheritanceRights,” Nairobi.______. 2007. Enhancing Urban Safety and Security. Global Report <strong>on</strong>Human Settlements.______. 2005. ‘Land tenure, housing rights and gender - nati<strong>on</strong>aland urban framework’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Land Tenure and Gender ReviewSeries: Latin America, Nairobi.______. 2005b. Financing Urban Shelter: Global Report <strong>on</strong> HumanSettlements. Nairobi.______. 2006. Analytical Perspective of Pro-Poor Slum UpgradingFrameworks. Nairobi: United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Human SettlementsProgramme.______. 1991. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> incremental development scheme: A case studyof Khuda ki Basti in Hyderabad, Pakistan, Nairobi, UN-HABITAT.United Nati<strong>on</strong>s. 1980. Report of the World C<strong>on</strong>ference of the United Nati<strong>on</strong>sDecade <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Women : Equality, Development and Peace,Doc A/Cof.94/35.United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Research Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Social Development (UNRISD).2006. ‘Land Tenure Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and Gender Equality,” Geneva,Switzerland.United States Agency <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development (USAID). 2006.Land and Business Formalizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor. A Strategic Overview Paper.______. 2007. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. From C<strong>on</strong>cepts toAssessments.V<strong>on</strong> Hoffman, Alexander. 1998. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Origins of American Housing Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper 98-2. Joint Canter <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Housing Studiesof Harvard University.Wallace, Jude and Williams<strong>on</strong>, 2006. ‘Building land markets,” LandUse Policy 23: 123-135.Wheeler, Samuel C. 1980. ‘Natural Property Rights as Body Rights,”Nous 14.Whitehead, Ann and Dzodzi Tsikata. 2003. ‘Policy Discourse <strong>on</strong> Women’sLand Rights in Sub-Saharan Africa: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Implicati<strong>on</strong>sof the Return to the Customary,” Journal of AgrarianChange 3.Williams, Rhodri. 2005. ‘Post-C<strong>on</strong>fl ict Property Restituti<strong>on</strong> and RefugeeReturn in Bosnia and Herzegovina: Implicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>alStandard-Setting and Practice,’ New York UniversityJournal of Internati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Politics 37: 441-553.Woodruff, Christopher. 2001. ‘Review of de Soto’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Mystery of Capital,’Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Literature 39: 1215-1223.Woolf, Virginia. 1938. Three Guineas.127


World Bank. 1993. ‘Housing: Enabling Markets to <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>,’ Housing policypaper, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.______. 2001. ‘Land, Security, Property Rights and the Urban Poor:Twenty Five Years of World Bank Experience’. World BankBriefi ng Note 8, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.______. 2002. World Development Report.______. 2003. ‘Land Policy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pro-Poor Development’ World Bank,Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.______. 2003a. Housing: Enabling Markets to <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.______. 2004. ‘Regi<strong>on</strong>al Study <strong>on</strong> Land Administrati<strong>on</strong>, Land Markets,and Collateralized Lending. East Asia and Pacifi c Regi<strong>on</strong>’World Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.______. 2004a. Water Resources Sector Strategy. Washingt<strong>on</strong>.______. 2006. ‘Afghanistan,’ Urban Policy Notes, Series 5.2,Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.World Business Council <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Sustainable Development (WBCSD). 2005.Doing Business with the Poor. A Field Guide.World Health Organisati<strong>on</strong>. 2000. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Urban Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Healthin a World of Increasing Globalizati<strong>on</strong>: Issues <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> DevelopingCountries. Bulletin Vol. 78. No.9. Geneva.Yu, S. and A. M. Karaos. 2004. ‘Establishing the role of communities ingovernance: the experience of the Homeless People’s Federati<strong>on</strong>Philippines.’ Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 16(1):107-119.Yuen, Belinda. 2002. ‘Singapore,’ In: Agus, M.R./J Doling, J./Lee, D.S. (eds.), Housing Policy Systems in South and East Asia,Palgrave Macmillan______. 2004. Planning Singapore Growth <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Better Living.’ In: MFreire and B Yuen (ed.) Enhancing Urban Management inEast Asia, Ashgate______. 2005. Squatters no more: Singapore Social Housing, WorldBank 3 rd Urban Research Symposium, Brasilia, Brazil.128


ChapterTHREETowards a GlobalSocial C<strong>on</strong>tract:Labour Rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor129


EXECUTIVE SUMMARYPurpose of this chapterChapter 3 is about labour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fight against poverty. Based <strong>on</strong> our review of employment andworking c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, we present two essential messages.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first is that governments and internati<strong>on</strong>alorganisati<strong>on</strong>s must address the decentwork deficits of those who work in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally, sincethe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, characterised by low productivity,low earnings and high risks, has beengrowing worldwide, emerging in many new guisesand in unexpected places. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d messageis <strong>on</strong>e of hope. It is about the new departure ininternati<strong>on</strong>al development strategies, in which wefind broad coaliti<strong>on</strong>s being <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med am<strong>on</strong>g governments,internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s, trade uni<strong>on</strong>s,employers and n<strong>on</strong>-governmental organisati<strong>on</strong>sthat are willing to take <strong>on</strong> the challenge of creatingand implementing policies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decent workand empowerment of the poor.We describe this new departure in internati<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment strategies as an emerging ‘GlobalSocial C<strong>on</strong>tract’ and propose that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor (sometimesreferred to by its acr<strong>on</strong>ym, CLEP) furtherdevelop the c<strong>on</strong>cept into a framework integratingaccess to justice, property rights, labour rightsand business rights.130Labour rights, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,empowerment and decent work: whatdo we mean?In Secti<strong>on</strong> 2, we define c<strong>on</strong>cepts used in this report.Labour rights include internati<strong>on</strong>ally agreedfundamental principles and rights at work, as wellas rights to social protecti<strong>on</strong>, income protecti<strong>on</strong>,workplace safety, decent working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s andparticipati<strong>on</strong> through representative organisati<strong>on</strong>sof workers, in nati<strong>on</strong>al policy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>a. Thisc<strong>on</strong>cept also takes into account and supportscommitments and policies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the creati<strong>on</strong> of full,productive and freely-chosen employment andtraining. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy refers to ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivities by workers and ec<strong>on</strong>omic units that are— in law or in practice — not covered or insufficientlycovered by <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal arrangements governingboth enterprise and employment relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment is that process throughwhich people are provided rights in an appropriatelegal framework, which they can claim andunderstand, and which they can find useful inimproving income and employment opportunities.It is a process recognised both <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally (legally)and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally (legitimately). We define decentwork as that available to all men and women,


and grounded in c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of freedom, securityand dignity. It has four pillars (a) fundamentalprinciples and rights at work under internati<strong>on</strong>allabour standards; (b) employment and incomeopportunities; (c) social protecti<strong>on</strong> and socialsecurity, and (d) social dialogue and tripartism.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce: who are wetalking about?<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> vast majority of the poor earn their living inthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy where average earnings arelow, productivity poor, working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s hazardous,and risks high. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 provides a globalpicture of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, highlighting itssize, segmentati<strong>on</strong>, and vulnerabilities. Womendominate the most-disadvantaged categories ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal work, notably industrial outwork andhome-based producti<strong>on</strong>. It is also in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy where child labour and b<strong>on</strong>ded labourare most prevalent, and where indigenous andtribal peoples are marginalized largely by discriminati<strong>on</strong>.Despite early predicti<strong>on</strong>s of its eventualdemise, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy c<strong>on</strong>tinues to grow.Poverty and labour rights: Towards aGlobal Social C<strong>on</strong>tractSecti<strong>on</strong> 4 describes a new departure in theinternati<strong>on</strong>al community regarding labour rightsand the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy; it features threenoteworthy elements: the Fundamental Principlesand Rights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> from 1998; the Decent<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda, first introduced in 1999, and the2002 Strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Labour Rights in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se elements are gaining increasingsupport from a broad coaliti<strong>on</strong> of governments,internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s, various employersand trade uni<strong>on</strong>s, as well as from n<strong>on</strong>-governmentalorganisati<strong>on</strong>s.As part of ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to achieve the MillenniumDevelopment Goals (MDGs), the 2005 WorldSummit of Heads of States agreed to make fulland productive employment and decent work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all a central objective of both nati<strong>on</strong>al andinternati<strong>on</strong>al policies and nati<strong>on</strong>al developmentand poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> strategies. In 2006 thiswas followed by the UN Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and SocialCouncil’s Ministerial Declarati<strong>on</strong>, which emphasisedfull and productive employment and decentwork <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all as an end in itself and a means toachieve the MDGs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda hasthere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e been accepted as a global aim; it nol<strong>on</strong>ger remains an ILO agenda al<strong>on</strong>e. Decent workhas been declared a goal not <strong>on</strong>ly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malwage sector, but also <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Growing recogniti<strong>on</strong> of the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour rightsto catalyse employment creati<strong>on</strong> in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, while protecting its workers, has ledto an emerging global social c<strong>on</strong>tract, creating abroad agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omics of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and thedebate <strong>on</strong> labour regulati<strong>on</strong>sFor the working poor, it is not the absence ofec<strong>on</strong>omic activity that is the source of theirpoverty, but the nature of their ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> link between work of low quality, orproductivity, and poverty is clear: if people earnedmore, poverty would decline. In Secti<strong>on</strong> 5, wereview research <strong>on</strong> the role of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>in setting ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social goals, and wedraw two major c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s. First, we suggestcauti<strong>on</strong> in interpreting this research, particularlythe cross-country studies. Cauti<strong>on</strong> shouldalso be exercised be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e translating the findingsinto country-level policy interventi<strong>on</strong>s withoutfirst c<strong>on</strong>sidering country-specific c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, theheterogeneity in the regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment andemployment arrangements. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, as a policyc<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>, we suggest a shift of focus from theprevailing ideological questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> regulati<strong>on</strong>-versus-deregulati<strong>on</strong>to questi<strong>on</strong>s about how regula-131


ti<strong>on</strong> can be used to promote decent work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theworking poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> debate, we suggest, shouldfocus <strong>on</strong> the quality of regulati<strong>on</strong>, and determiningthe right balance between security, supportivestructures, and flexibility in both the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal andin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Principles and practices of labourrights and legal empowermentOur proposed strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment,introduced in Secti<strong>on</strong> 6, is based <strong>on</strong>comm<strong>on</strong> core principles, while remaining flexibleto fit different ec<strong>on</strong>omic, social and political c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.It is participatory, inclusive and gendersensitive.Some of the principles are basic: theyinclude the need to combine promoti<strong>on</strong> of changewith management of change, labour rights withproperty rights, and flexibility with security.Examples are presented to show that re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m isunderway; they illustrate how different policiescan be used to provide working people with legalidentity (India, the Philippines and Thailand),voice and representati<strong>on</strong> (India), social protecti<strong>on</strong>(Brazil, Chile, Ghana, India, Mexico, thePhilippines), and new ways to resolve disputes(Tajikistan). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also show how different policiescan be used to improve the functi<strong>on</strong>ing of labourmarket instituti<strong>on</strong>s (Chile and Thailand), and tostrike a balance between protecti<strong>on</strong> and flexibilityin resp<strong>on</strong>se to changing realities (Spain). Implicati<strong>on</strong>sare drawn <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> other countries.Our recommendati<strong>on</strong>sWe propose that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> accepts the followingrecommendati<strong>on</strong>s:Policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>sStrengthen identity, voice, representati<strong>on</strong> anddialogue: For the poor, labour and human capitalare the greatest assets, and these must be effectivelyrecognised and supported to help the poorwork their way out of poverty. First and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emost,the State must recognise their legal identity asworkers — the initial c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> through whichthey can engage in legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Rights tofreedom of associati<strong>on</strong> and collective bargainingare also essential to strengthen the voice of theworking poor and to facilitate their dialogue with<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy operators and public authorities.Improve the quality of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> and thefuncti<strong>on</strong> of instituti<strong>on</strong>s: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is also need to improvethe quality of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> and to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cefundamental principles and rights at work.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> aim is to create synergies between protecti<strong>on</strong>and productivity of the working poor and their assets.Critical and self-critical reviews of the qualityof instituti<strong>on</strong>s and regulati<strong>on</strong>s should examineimpacts <strong>on</strong> prosperity and labour protecti<strong>on</strong>.Support applicati<strong>on</strong> of a minimum package oflabour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy: Rightsshould be established in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy thatupholds the Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Fundamental Principlesand Rights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the three crucial aspectsrelated to working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s: health and safetyat work, hours of work, and minimum income.Such a minimum floor <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment should berealistic and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable. Progressive compliance— towards a fuller set of labour rights buildingup<strong>on</strong> this minimum floor - would be expected.Strengthen access to opportunities: Key to thelegal empowerment process is the promoti<strong>on</strong> ofchange and dynamism. This may be achieved by<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ging links between private initiative and publicpolicy to encourage expansi<strong>on</strong> of employment ina growing and inclusive ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decent work are also advanced by provisi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>, training and retraining, as well asby ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to combat discriminati<strong>on</strong> and promoteefficient labour markets.132


Support inclusive social protecti<strong>on</strong>: Universallyaccepted instruments, such as the UniversalDeclarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Human Rights, recognise socialsecurity as a fundamental societal right <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, instituti<strong>on</strong>s and resp<strong>on</strong>sive mechanismsprotecting the poor from ec<strong>on</strong>omic shocks, aswell as guaranteed access to medical care, healthinsurance, old age pensi<strong>on</strong>s, and social services,must be upheld. Social protecti<strong>on</strong> mechanismsmust be open to all types of workers and notsolely <strong>on</strong> the basis of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal evidence of employment.From a systemic perspective, rights to pensi<strong>on</strong>sand health protecti<strong>on</strong> should be granted <strong>on</strong>the principle of universality to people as citizensrather than as workers.Promote legal empowerment as driver <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> genderequality: A key challenge is to ensure that ILOlabour standards, promoting equality of opportunityand treatment, are effectively extended to allworking poor, especially women, in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. This requires knowledge of whereworking poor women are c<strong>on</strong>centrated in thelabour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce, how they are inserted into the globalproducti<strong>on</strong> and with what c<strong>on</strong>sequences. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reis a growing internati<strong>on</strong>al movement, inspired bythe Self-Employed Women’s Associati<strong>on</strong> (SEWA)of India, to increase the visibility and voice offemale in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers and to address their particulardisadvantages, in terms of opportunities,rights, protecti<strong>on</strong> and voice.Support legal empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenouspeoples: Although indigenous peoples are disproporti<strong>on</strong>atelyrepresented am<strong>on</strong>g the poor, theirneeds and priorities are generally not reflected inef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to combat poverty. ILO’s Indigenous andTribal Peoples C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> provides guidance andstrategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment with respect tolabour rights and protecti<strong>on</strong> of employment.Process recommendati<strong>on</strong>sPromote nati<strong>on</strong>al development frameworks <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legal empowerment and decent work: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> decentwork agenda is best defined at nati<strong>on</strong>allevel through social dialogue. Its aim is to makeemployment a central goal of ec<strong>on</strong>omic policies,recognising that progressive improvement in thequality of work, including labour rights and returnsto labour, is a main route out of poverty andof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality. Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Country Programmes(DWCPs) are major tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> driving this re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mprocess <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward in partnership with relevant nati<strong>on</strong>aland internati<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>s.Mobilise the regi<strong>on</strong>al levels to support nati<strong>on</strong>alre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m programmes: Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategies addressingemployment and labour rights will need to beadapted to regi<strong>on</strong>al and local priorities. Regi<strong>on</strong>alDevelopment Banks, regi<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s, likethe African Uni<strong>on</strong>, as well as the UN and itsagencies, funds and programmes can be tappedas instituti<strong>on</strong>al champi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an integrated re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>magenda <strong>on</strong> legal empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor.Mobilise the principal actors of the global system,particularly the World Bank and the ILO, to workbetter together <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decent work: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank’sPoverty Reducti<strong>on</strong> Strategies and ILO’s DWCPsare crucial instruments <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. <strong>Legal</strong> empowermentthrough labour rights requires closecooperati<strong>on</strong> between governments, employersand workers, both nati<strong>on</strong>ally and locally. Capacitybuilding support from the leading global instituti<strong>on</strong>swill strengthen the ability of traditi<strong>on</strong>alsocial partners to reach out to workers in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. A key to a successful re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mprocess at nati<strong>on</strong>al level is better policy coherenceat global level.Support voluntary initiatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentthrough labour rights: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO’s FundamentalPrinciples and Rights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> inspires many133


voluntary code-of-c<strong>on</strong>duct initiatives. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y arepursuing important strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> motivating improvementsin the per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance of multinati<strong>on</strong>alcorporati<strong>on</strong>s, and in encouraging businesses tobecome more sensitive to ethical c<strong>on</strong>sumer reacti<strong>on</strong>s.Such initiatives should be strengthenedand coherence between them promoted so as toavoid dangers of proliferati<strong>on</strong>. Voluntary initiativesshould be seen as stepping st<strong>on</strong>es <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalempowerment, rather than a means to avoid legalobligati<strong>on</strong>s.Mobilise d<strong>on</strong>or countries to promote legal empowermentand decent work: D<strong>on</strong>or countries havemany opportunities to support legal empowermentand the inclusi<strong>on</strong> of a decent work agendain regi<strong>on</strong>al and nati<strong>on</strong>al strategies.Promote better understanding of costs and benefitsof legal empowerment through decent work:Expected benefits of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m from legal empowermentthrough decent work require further study,particularly their effects <strong>on</strong> productivity andprosperity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> costs of policy initiatives to startand sustain re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m processes also need to be betterunderstood.Strengthen the statistical base <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment:Better nati<strong>on</strong>al statistics and indicators <strong>on</strong>size, compositi<strong>on</strong>, and c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy would improve visibility and facilitateplanning, particularly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulating policiespromoting <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s to further developthe Global Social C<strong>on</strong>tract<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a tripartite c<strong>on</strong>sensus from employer,worker and government representatives <strong>on</strong> theneed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and effective legal systemwhich guarantees all citizens and enterprises thatc<strong>on</strong>tracts are h<strong>on</strong>oured and upheld, the rule oflaw is respected and property rights are secured.This is a key c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> not <strong>on</strong>ly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> attractinginvestment, but also <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> generating certaintyand nurturing trust and fairness in society. 1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>growing recogniti<strong>on</strong> of the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour rightsto catalyse employment creati<strong>on</strong> in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, while protecting its workers, has led toan emerging global social c<strong>on</strong>tract; effectively,it is a broad agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment.Labour rights, business rights, propertyrights and business rights, taken together, can<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the basis of this new social c<strong>on</strong>tract.Five fundamental areas of acti<strong>on</strong> could underpinthe new social c<strong>on</strong>tract: (1) Strengthen identity,voice, representati<strong>on</strong> and dialogue; (2) Strengthenquality of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> and effectiveen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of fundamental principles and rightsat work; (3) Support applicati<strong>on</strong> of a minimumpackage of labour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy;(4) Strengthen access to opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>decent work, educati<strong>on</strong>, training and retraining,while combating discriminati<strong>on</strong> to ensure efficientlabour markets, and (5) Support inclusivesocial protecti<strong>on</strong>.We describe the new departure in internati<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment strategies, centred <strong>on</strong> the Decent<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda, as a Global Social C<strong>on</strong>tract andpropose that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> (or CLEP) furtherdevelop the c<strong>on</strong>cept by integrating access tojustice, property rights, labour rights and businessrights into a framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor. Our proposals are firmly basedin the internati<strong>on</strong>al human rights traditi<strong>on</strong>, whichthe State, as primary duty bearer, is obliged toprotect and promote.Finally, we reflect <strong>on</strong> the words that <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the c<strong>on</strong>ceptGlobal Social C<strong>on</strong>tract. ‘C<strong>on</strong>tract’ suggestsan emphasis <strong>on</strong> mutual resp<strong>on</strong>sibility. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> state,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, has a duty to protect, and citizenshave the right to protecti<strong>on</strong>. But there are obliga-134


ti<strong>on</strong>s that follow from this, and employers andemployees are also tied by mutual obligati<strong>on</strong>s.Similarly, large businesses have a duty not toexploit smaller <strong>on</strong>es with which they have producti<strong>on</strong>or distributi<strong>on</strong> ties. Our inclusi<strong>on</strong> of the word‘global’ places a focus <strong>on</strong> the role and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilityof the actors at internati<strong>on</strong>al, regi<strong>on</strong>al,nati<strong>on</strong>al and local levels, while ‘social’ callsattenti<strong>on</strong> to the aim of this initiative, which is toimprove the social c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of people in poorcountries. Importantly, we have placed the word‘towards’ be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e ‘a global social c<strong>on</strong>tract’ in thetitle of our chapter to emphasise development,process and time horiz<strong>on</strong>s.1. Introducti<strong>on</strong>: Purpose ofour focus <strong>on</strong> Labour Rights<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> has identified the issue of labourrights as <strong>on</strong>e of four elements of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor. Almost half the world’s populati<strong>on</strong>of 6 billi<strong>on</strong> lives <strong>on</strong> less than US$2 a day,while a fifth survives <strong>on</strong> US$1 a day or less. Formost people mired in poverty, the <strong>on</strong>ly asset theyown is their own labour. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank estimatesthat <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> over 70 percent of the poor, findingwork — either wage work or self-employment— is the main pathway out of poverty; 2 but thestark reality, according to the ILO, is that some500 milli<strong>on</strong> of the working poor are currently unableto achieve this goal.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality in the work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce has always beenpredominant in developing countries — but itis also growing in developed ec<strong>on</strong>omies. For thepoor, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment is the predominant<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of employment, in which they have no legalidentity as entrepreneurs or as workers. Also,the wider policy envir<strong>on</strong>ment and instituti<strong>on</strong>allandscape, including systems of legal and socialprotecti<strong>on</strong>, are biased towards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal incorporatedfirms and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal organised workers. Often,the poor are shut out of the legally recognisedsystems that would allow them to benefit fromtheir hard work. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are mostly excluded fromthe legal mechanisms that protect their assetsrelated to property or labour. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y lack access toa fully-functi<strong>on</strong>ing justice system that protectstheir rights regardless of status in life.135<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO notes that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality is mainly a governanceissue; 3 it is traced to laws and instituti<strong>on</strong>alframeworks that are not resp<strong>on</strong>sive to thec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in which the working poor have alwaysbeen or are increasingly found. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> boundaries oflaws and instituti<strong>on</strong>al frameworks remain unyieldingto the growing number of poor who are found


outside their protective reach. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bankhas shown that, while in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality is str<strong>on</strong>gly correlatedwith low productivity and a high degree ofpoverty, 4 governance and quality of regulati<strong>on</strong> canplay an important role in engendering prosperityand protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce.Our aim is to suggest how to address the viciouscircle of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, lack of legal protecti<strong>on</strong>, andpoverty. Our point of departure is that poverty isboth a market failure and a public policy failure,which the internati<strong>on</strong>al community has begun torecognise. Within the past 10 years, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example,attempts have been made to obtain global c<strong>on</strong>sensus<strong>on</strong> the Fundamental Principles and Rightsof <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and to gain widespread endorsement ofthe Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda. Furthermore, there isevidence of growing recogniti<strong>on</strong> of the need to extendlabour rights to the work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are strategic priorities and they c<strong>on</strong>stitutethe three pillars of an emerging global social c<strong>on</strong>tractwith wide support in the internati<strong>on</strong>al community,including governments in rich and poorcountries, the UN family, internati<strong>on</strong>al financialinstituti<strong>on</strong>s, employers, trade uni<strong>on</strong>s, and NGOs.This chapter c<strong>on</strong>tains seven secti<strong>on</strong>s. Secti<strong>on</strong>2 defines labour rights, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,empowerment and decent work, while Secti<strong>on</strong> 3explains who we are talking about — the size andcompositi<strong>on</strong> of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce and themany segments found therein. Next, Secti<strong>on</strong> 4highlights new initiatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour rights in thefight against poverty and describes the internati<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>sensus that has developed around thisnew agenda — <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorthrough labour rights. Following this, Secti<strong>on</strong> 5examines the ec<strong>on</strong>omic rati<strong>on</strong>ale <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentthrough labour rights, and summarizesthe ec<strong>on</strong>omic debates surrounding labourregulati<strong>on</strong>s. In Secti<strong>on</strong> 6 we provide recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> the principles and practices of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m,as well as case materials <strong>on</strong> selected countryexperiences reflecting appropriate resp<strong>on</strong>ses tothe extensi<strong>on</strong> of labour rights and standards toall <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of employment or work arrangements.Finally, Secti<strong>on</strong> 7 sets out our recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> policies and processes needed to carry out theproposed plan of acti<strong>on</strong>.Our recommendati<strong>on</strong>s are aimed at taking thisagenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward in a manner coordinated withthe other working groups of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong><strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment that are focused <strong>on</strong> accessto justice, property rights and business rights. Weargue that is it important to merge the free marketapproach with a human rights approach bycombining: (a) promoti<strong>on</strong> of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth toimprove productivity and job creati<strong>on</strong> stimulatedby competiti<strong>on</strong>, specialisati<strong>on</strong> and free trade, and(b) management of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth to obtainwidely-shared prosperity through the advancementof decent work, social dialogue, inclusi<strong>on</strong>,and social protecti<strong>on</strong> of all workers.136


2. Labour Rights, In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy, Empowermentand Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>: What dowe mean?In this secti<strong>on</strong> we define the key terms andc<strong>on</strong>cepts that underpin our discussi<strong>on</strong>s; namely,labour rights, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, legal empowermentand decent work.Labour Rights<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>cept of labour rights includes the internati<strong>on</strong>allyagreed-up<strong>on</strong> Fundamental Principles andRights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> 5 as well as rights to social protecti<strong>on</strong>and income protecti<strong>on</strong>, workplace safety,decent working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and the participati<strong>on</strong>through representative organisati<strong>on</strong>s in nati<strong>on</strong>alpolicy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ums. This c<strong>on</strong>cept also takes into accountand supports commitments and policies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the creati<strong>on</strong> of full, productive and freely chosenemployment as well as work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce development.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se rights can be expressed through differentmechanisms at the internati<strong>on</strong>al, nati<strong>on</strong>al and locallevels, such as those relating to internati<strong>on</strong>allabour standards, nati<strong>on</strong>al labour law, nati<strong>on</strong>aland local regulati<strong>on</strong>s and labour agreementsbetween employers and workers. Socially resp<strong>on</strong>siblecorporati<strong>on</strong>s and other organisati<strong>on</strong>s mayalso express them in a voluntary way.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is defined as comprising‘all ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities by workers andec<strong>on</strong>omic units that are — in law or in practice— not covered or insufficiently covered by <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malarrangements’ regulating both enterprise and employmentrelati<strong>on</strong>ships. 6 In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment 7c<strong>on</strong>sists of two broad categories, the self-employedin in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal (small unregistered) enterprisesand wageworkers in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal (unprotected)jobs, including disguised wageworkers. Underthis expanded internati<strong>on</strong>al statistical framework,the specific criteria used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> determining whatis (or is not) an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprise and what is(or is not) an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal job are set by countries,including: what size of enterprise and what typeof registrati<strong>on</strong> should be used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> determiningwhat is an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprise; and what type ofc<strong>on</strong>tract or social protecti<strong>on</strong> coverage should beused <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> determining what is an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal job.<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment is defined as a processthrough which people are provided rightsin an appropriate legal framework, which theyunderstand, can claim, find useful in improvingtheir income and livelihoods, and which arerecognised both <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally (legally) and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally(legitimately). Thus, legal empowerment requiresthat in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> is available and appropriateinstituti<strong>on</strong>s are established to ensure that commercialand employment c<strong>on</strong>tracts are respected,property titles and businesses are registered,and access to social protecti<strong>on</strong> and justice is athand. By this, people are able to engage publicand private sector agents and participate in fullyfuncti<strong>on</strong>ing market instituti<strong>on</strong>s.All too often, the poor do not know of, or are notable to understand regulati<strong>on</strong>s. Moreover, theydo not have c<strong>on</strong>tracts, and lack resort to disputemediati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> absence of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and ofappropriate instituti<strong>on</strong>s curtails the exercise ofchoice. Yet, the existence of choice, the exerciseof choice, and the achievement of choice in thedifferent domains of a pers<strong>on</strong>’s life (includingwork) lie at the heart of legal empowerment. 8It is important to emphasise that empowerment isboth a process and a goal. It is a process wherebykey stakeholders are involved in framing coherent137


and sustainable soluti<strong>on</strong>s and people are engagedin a c<strong>on</strong>tinuous ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t to find resp<strong>on</strong>ses to evolvingissues. However, it is a goal in that socialdialogue and participati<strong>on</strong> is an objective in andof itself — <strong>on</strong>e of the four pillars of decent workas defined below.According to <strong>on</strong>e definiti<strong>on</strong>, empowerment isbased <strong>on</strong> four c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, namely, access toin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, systems of accountability, venues <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>inclusi<strong>on</strong>/participati<strong>on</strong> and local organisati<strong>on</strong>alcapacity. 9In the domain of labour rights, empowerment issecured when the fundamental principles andrights at work are respected. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se so-called‘enabling rights’ can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered avenues toempowerment. 10 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y c<strong>on</strong>stitute the basic rightto participati<strong>on</strong> and freedom of choice in thearena of work that every<strong>on</strong>e should enjoy.Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Organisati<strong>on</strong> introducedthe noti<strong>on</strong> of decent work in 1999. 11 Its premise:opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all women and men to work inc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of freedom, security and dignity, hasbecome a global goal endorsed by the internati<strong>on</strong>alcommunity. Decent work rests <strong>on</strong> four pillars:(a) fundamental principles and rights at work andinternati<strong>on</strong>al labour standards; (b) employmentand income opportunities; (c) social protecti<strong>on</strong>and social security; and (d) social dialogue andtripartism.3. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and Poverty:Whom are we talkingabout? What is theiridentity?This secti<strong>on</strong> presents an overview of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, including its size and structure as wellas the workers in it. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> (CLEP) haschosen to focus <strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy becauseof the str<strong>on</strong>g link between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and poverty.Also, as the World Bank has found in a studyof 75 countries, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality is correlated with lowproductivity and low GDP growth. 12According to ILO estimates, there are some 500milli<strong>on</strong> working people living in households thatearn less than US$1 per capita per day. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> vastmajority of these ‘working poor’ earn their livingin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyis associated not <strong>on</strong>ly with low productivity butalso low earnings, poor working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, highrisks, and little (if any) legal or social protecti<strong>on</strong>s.While there is not a complete overlap betweenworking in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and being poor,or working in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and escapingpoverty, the link between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and povertyis quite significant and stark.What follows is a summary of recent estimates ofthe size of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy in 25 developingcountries 13 and recent analyses of changesin in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment over time in 20 of thesecountries. 14 Official nati<strong>on</strong>al data were used toestimate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment in each of thecountries. 15Size and significance in developingcountriesIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment, broadly defined, comprises<strong>on</strong>e-half to three-quarters of n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural em-138


ployment in developing countries: specifically, 47percent in the Middle East and North Africa; 51percent in Latin America; 71 percent in Asia, and72 percent in sub-Saharan Africa. If South Africais excluded, the share of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment inn<strong>on</strong>-agricultural employment rises to 78 percentin sub-Saharan Africa; and if comparable datawere available <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> countries (other than India), inSouth Asia, the regi<strong>on</strong>al average <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Asia wouldlikely be much higher.Some countries include in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employmentin agriculture in their estimates. Thissignificantly increases the proporti<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment: from 83 percent of n<strong>on</strong>-agriculturalemployment to 93 percent of total employment inIndia; from 55 to 62 percent in Mexico, and from28 to 34 percent in South Africa. 16<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> two main segments of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment,classified by employment status, are the self-employedand the wageworkers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-employedinclude employers, or owner-operators of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises who hire others; own-account workers,or owner-operators in single-pers<strong>on</strong> units orfamily businesses/farms who do not hire others,and unpaid c<strong>on</strong>tributing family workers, whoare family workers in family businesses or farmswithout pay.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> wageworker segment c<strong>on</strong>sists largely ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employees — those who are unprotectedin their work with a known employer that couldbe an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprise, a c<strong>on</strong>tractingagency, or a household; casual wage worker, orthose wage workers with no fixed employer whosell their labour <strong>on</strong> a daily or seas<strong>on</strong>al basis, andindustrial outworkers, who are sub-c<strong>on</strong>tractedto produce <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a piece-rate from their homes orsmall workshops.Compositi<strong>on</strong> of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omyIn all developing regi<strong>on</strong>s, self-employment comprisesa greater share of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment(outside of agriculture) than wage employment:specifically, self-employment represents 70percent of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment in sub-SaharanAfrica, 62 percent in North Africa, 60 percent inLatin America, and 59 percent in Asia. In China,it is estimated that between 1990 and 2004,urban in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment increased by 125.55milli<strong>on</strong> people, which was 133 percent of allincreased employment. 17 Excluding South Africa,where black-owned businesses were prohibitedduring the apartheid era and have <strong>on</strong>ly recentlybegun to be recognised and reported, the share ofself-employment in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment increasedto 81 percent in sub-Saharan Africa.Self-employment represents nearly <strong>on</strong>e-third oftotal n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural employment worldwide. It isless important in developed countries (12 percentof total n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural employment) than indeveloping countries where it comprises as muchas 53 percent of n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural employment insub-Saharan Africa, 44 percent in Latin America,32 percent in Asia, and 31 percent in NorthAfrica.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal wage employment, including disguisedwage employment, is also significant in thedeveloping world: comprising 30 to 40 percent ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment (outside of agriculture). 18Home-based workers and street vendors are twoof the largest sub-groups of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce:with home-based workers being the morenumerous but street vendors the more visible ofthe two. Together they represent 10-25 percentof the n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce in developingcountries and over five percent of the total work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cein developed countries.139


Segmentati<strong>on</strong> in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal LabourMarket 19Available evidence suggests that there is markedsegmentati<strong>on</strong> within in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal labour marketsin terms of average earnings across the differentemployment statuses. Specifically, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployers have the highest earnings <strong>on</strong> average;followed by their employees and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employeesof <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal firms; then own account operatorsfollowed by casual wage workers, and industrialoutworkers: see Figure 1. An inverse hierarchy isobserved <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the risk of being from a poor household:employers are least likely to be from poorhouseholds and, especially if they are the primarybreadwinners, industrial outworkers are the mostlikely to be from poor households.In Tunisia, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employers earnfour times the minimum wage and over two times(2.2) the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal wage. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir employees earnroughly the minimum wage, while industrial outworkers— mostly women home-workers — earnless than <strong>on</strong>e-third (30 percent) of the minimumwage. In Columbia and India, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employersearn four-to-five times the minimum wage, whileown account operators earn <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e-and-a-halftimes the minimum wage. 20Research findings suggest that it is difficult tomove up these segments due to structural barriers(state, market, and social) and/or cumulativedisadvantages. Many workers, especially women,remain trapped in the lower-earning and morerisky segments.Figure 1 Segmentati<strong>on</strong> of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: By Sex, Average Earnings and Poverty RiskPoverty RiskAverage EarningsSegmentati<strong>on</strong> by SexLOWHIGHEmployersPredominantly MenIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal EmployeesOwn Account OperatorsMen and WomenCasual Day LabourersUnpaid Family <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ersPredominantlyWomenNote: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy may also be segmented by race, ethnicity, caste or religi<strong>on</strong>.Source: Chen et al 2004, 2005.140


Box 1 Different Categories of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ersand Corresp<strong>on</strong>ding ChallengesCategories of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ersEmployees of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprisesCasual day labourersHomeworkers or Home-based producersDomestic workersC<strong>on</strong>tract labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal fi rmsMigrant labourersC<strong>on</strong>ceptual/Practical ChallengesAbility of employers to complyCost of complianceZero-cost of n<strong>on</strong>-complianceEpisodic/seas<strong>on</strong>al workNo fixed employerAmbiguous employment status:neither dependent nor independentAmbiguous relati<strong>on</strong>ship with c<strong>on</strong>tractor:commercial vs. employmentUncertainty as to who is principally resp<strong>on</strong>sible:c<strong>on</strong>tractor or lead firm?Household as employerMultiple employersUncertainty re who is principally resp<strong>on</strong>sible:c<strong>on</strong>tractor or <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal firm?Intersecti<strong>on</strong> of immigrati<strong>on</strong> status/regime and labour status/regimeSource: Martha Chen, ‘Labour standards and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> nature of the challenge.’ Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor, November 2006.Another type of segmentati<strong>on</strong> is based <strong>on</strong> differencesbetween women and men within thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy reflecting gender norms whichinfluence both the supply of and the demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>labour. As a general rule in developing countries,men tend to be over-represented in the top segmentsof the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy; women tend tobe over-represented in the bottom segment.More specifically, relatively high shares of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployers are men and relatively high sharesof industrial outworkers are women. In India, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, 6 percent of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employers, 19percent of own account operators, 16 percent ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal wage workers, and 59 percent of industrialoutworkers are women. 21 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se stylised factsare depicted graphically in Figure 1.A legal empowerment agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> workers in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy must take into account the differentcategories of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers and the specificrealities of their work arrangements. In Box1, below, there are illustrati<strong>on</strong>s of the c<strong>on</strong>ceptualand practical challenges in c<strong>on</strong>sidering labourrights and protecti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the different categoriesof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers. A proper understanding ofthe nuances and challenges should lead not <strong>on</strong>lyto appropriate legal resp<strong>on</strong>ses but also to a widerset of policy tools and instituti<strong>on</strong>al strategies. 22141


In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of Labour Markets<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a widespread assumpti<strong>on</strong> that thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is counter-cyclical: that is, itexpands during ec<strong>on</strong>omic down turns and c<strong>on</strong>tractsduring periods of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. To besure, empirical evidence from a set of developedand developing countries indicates that the levelof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment, taking self-employmentas a proxy indicator, decreases when GDPper capita goes up and vice versa. 23 However, asshown above, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is made upof both self-employed and wage workers, therebydem<strong>on</strong>strating limitati<strong>on</strong>s to the use of self-employmental<strong>on</strong>e as a proxy indicator. Furthermore,the co-relati<strong>on</strong>ship between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employmentand growth is not straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward. Recent analysesof data over time from different developingcountries suggest a more complex and dynamicrelati<strong>on</strong>ship between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth. While ec<strong>on</strong>omic downturns are almost invariablyassociated with an expansi<strong>on</strong> of employmentin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy (due to the growthin survival activities), steady rates of ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth may be accompanied, not by a reducti<strong>on</strong>,but actually an expansi<strong>on</strong> of employmentin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. This is because duringec<strong>on</strong>omic upswings, certain <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment may expand, such as the more entrepreneurialsmall firms as well as sub-c<strong>on</strong>tractedand outsourced activities linked to the globalproducti<strong>on</strong> system. 24 This may well dem<strong>on</strong>stratethat increasingly the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is enteringinto a symbiotic relati<strong>on</strong>ship with the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal,where the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer makes use of the latter toimprove profits and growth strategies, perhapseven to avoid respecting labour standards andregulati<strong>on</strong>s. In these countries, it was <strong>on</strong>ly aftera sustained period of higher levels of growth thataggregate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> declined. 25 This importantfinding is further elaborated in Box 2.Box 2 Relati<strong>on</strong>ship betweenin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and growth:Cross-country evidenceC<strong>on</strong>sider the findings from 20 countries in Asia,Africa, and Latin America at two points in time— generally in the 1980s and the 1990s. Foreach of the countries, the rate of change in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>is compared to the average per capitaGDP growth (Heintz and Pollin 2003). Most of thecountries (14 out of 20) experienced growth in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>,while four experienced a decline and twoexperienced little, if any, change. What is interestingto note is that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> increased in threecountries with respectable per capita growth rates(>2 percent) and declined in two countries with poorper capita growth rates (


In North American, European Uni<strong>on</strong>, and otherOECD countries, available evidence suggeststhat n<strong>on</strong>-standard employment is <strong>on</strong> the rise.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> term ‘n<strong>on</strong>-standard work’ as comm<strong>on</strong>ly used,includes: a) jobs entailing an employment arrangementthat diverges from regular, year-round,full-time employment with a single employer butwithout security; and b) self-employment, withor without employees. (Carré and Herranz 2002.)<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> comm<strong>on</strong> categories of n<strong>on</strong>-standard wagework are temporary, fixed-term and part-time.Increasingly, inter-firm sub-c<strong>on</strong>tracted work inthe service sector (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, janitorial servicesand home care) and the manufacturing sector(garment making, electr<strong>on</strong>ic assembly) is alsoincluded.What follows is a brief summary of trends in threecategories of n<strong>on</strong>-standard work — part-timework, temporary work, and self-employment — inEurope, including differences by sex. (Carré andHerranz 2002, Carré 2006.)Part-Time <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>: Since the early 1970s, therehas been a marked growth in the proporti<strong>on</strong> ofpart-time workers in total employment. By 1998,part-time workers accounted <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 16 percent oftotal employment in EU countries and 14 percentof total employment in OECD countries.Temporary Employment: For the EU as a whole,and in a majority of EU nati<strong>on</strong>s, the share ofworkers in temporary employment, including bothdirect hire and agency hire, increased from themid-1980s to the late 1990s. By 1998, temporaryemployment accounted <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> around10 percent of total employment in EU countries.Self-Employment: Self-employment, includingboth employers and own account workers, has increasedin many OECD countries over the past 25years. 26 Indeed, outside of agriculture, self-employmenthas grown at a faster rate than total employmentin 14 (out of 24) OECD countries wheredata were available. Also, as self-employment hasbeen growing, so has the share of own accountself-employment within total self-employment. Asa result, in OECD countries today, more self-employedpers<strong>on</strong>s are own account workers, ratherthan employers.In additi<strong>on</strong> to these comm<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of n<strong>on</strong>-standardwork in OECD countries, there are other<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of n<strong>on</strong>-standard work — notably, casualday labour, industrial outwork, and other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms ofsub-c<strong>on</strong>tracted work — <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> which data are not soreadily available.In sum, the purely counter-cyclical model of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malitydoes not hold. At least in the short term,countries dem<strong>on</strong>strate significant variati<strong>on</strong> in theirpatterns of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> even under c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sof steady ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Also, different segmentsof the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy dem<strong>on</strong>strate substantialvariati<strong>on</strong> in their cyclical patterns. Certainsegments of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy expand duringdownturns in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy: particularly survivalactivities and sub-c<strong>on</strong>tracted activities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> firmstrying to cope with the downturn. Certain othersegments of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy expand duringupturns in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy: notably, dynamic independententerprises and sub-c<strong>on</strong>tracted activitieslinked to global value chains.Gendered patternsIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of Labour Markets by Sex<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> last two decades have seen a marked increasein women’s labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce participati<strong>on</strong>: most significantlyin the Americas and Western Europe andmore modestly in Sub-Saharan Africa, SoutheastAsia, and East Asia. 27 Only in two regi<strong>on</strong>s — EasternEurope and South Asia — has the women’slabour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce participati<strong>on</strong> rate actually fallen. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>marked increase in women’s labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce partici-143


pati<strong>on</strong> worldwide has given rise to the noti<strong>on</strong> ofthe ‘feminisati<strong>on</strong> of the labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce’. But thisnoti<strong>on</strong> has been defined and used in two distinctways. First, to refer to the situati<strong>on</strong> in which theratio of women’s labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce participati<strong>on</strong> rate tomen’s labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce participati<strong>on</strong> rate increases overtime. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, to refer to a situati<strong>on</strong> in which thestructure of the labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce itself is ‘feminised’:that is, when jobs take <strong>on</strong> features associated withwomen’s work such as low pay, drudgery, uncertainty,and precariousness. 28Whether or not there is a causal link between theincrease in women’s labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce participati<strong>on</strong>and the growing precariousness or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality ofwork is not clear — and has been hotly debated.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> pervasive segmentati<strong>on</strong> of labour marketsby gender, which we discussed above, suggeststhat women’s labour did not simply substitute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>men’s labour. Rather, that there has been someparallel process at work creating low-paid andpoor quality in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> (primarily) women. 29Estimates of changes over time in the degree ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> within the female and male labour<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce are not available. However, we have seenabove that growth in certain <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment — notably, sub-c<strong>on</strong>tracted worklinked to the global producti<strong>on</strong> system — expandsduring periods of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, especiallywhen growth is driven by trade and financialliberalisati<strong>on</strong>. What is important to note hereis that women workers tend to be overrepresentedin global producti<strong>on</strong> systems, at least in the earlystages of trade liberalisati<strong>on</strong> when a premium isplaced <strong>on</strong> export-oriented light manufacturingand low-skilled (and low-paid) workers. 30In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Employment in Developing CountriesIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment is generally a larger sourceof employment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women than <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> men in thedeveloping world. Other than in the Middle Eastand North Africa, where 42 percent of womenworkers (and 48 percent of male workers) arein in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment, 60 percent or more ofwomen n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural workers in the developingworld are in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally employed. Am<strong>on</strong>g n<strong>on</strong>-agriculturalworkers, in sub-Saharan Africa, 84 percentof women workers are in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally employedcompared to 63 percent of male workers; in LatinAmerica, 58 percent of women workers comparedto 48 percent of men; and in Asia, 73 percent ofwomen workers compared to 70 percent of maleworkers.N<strong>on</strong>-Standard Employment in DevelopedCountriesIn virtually all EU and OECD countries, the incidenceof part-time work is much higher am<strong>on</strong>gwomen than men: in some countries it is twice ashigh. By 1998, women represented 82 percentof all part-time workers in EU countries. Further,rates of part-time work are high <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women, butnot men, in their prime working years.Temporary employment, like part-time work,is primarily a female phenomen<strong>on</strong>, althoughthere is wide variati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g EU countries. Inall countries except Austria, the incidence oftemporary employment am<strong>on</strong>g females is higherthan am<strong>on</strong>g all workers. And, like part-time work,temporary employment is c<strong>on</strong>centrated in the service-producingindustries. Interestingly, womenaccount <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the majority of agency temps incountries where such employment c<strong>on</strong>centratesin services, while men account <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the majority ofagency temps in countries where such employmentc<strong>on</strong>centrates in manufacturing and c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>.Effectively, ‘the gender compositi<strong>on</strong> ofemployment mirrors that of the sectors in whichtemporary agency assignments take place.’ 31In 1997, women comprised <strong>on</strong>e in three of144


self-employed pers<strong>on</strong>s in OECD countries andtheir proporti<strong>on</strong> is growing. For EU countries asa whole, the incidence of own-account work isgreater <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> men (11 percent) than <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women (7percent). But, in some countries, a higher proporti<strong>on</strong>of women than men are own-account workers.Age is a factor in own-account work: thoseaged 45 and above are more likely than youngerpers<strong>on</strong>s to be working <strong>on</strong> their own account. 32Indigenous and Tribal PeoplesFinally, <strong>on</strong>e specific group in society that hasoften suffered from abject poverty and profounddiscriminati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sists of indigenous and tribalpeoples. It is estimated that there are 350 milli<strong>on</strong>indigenous and tribal peoples (ITPs) representing5000 ethnic groups. While they representfive percent of the world’s populati<strong>on</strong>, they account<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 15 percent of the world’s poor. Poverty,inequality, and various types of injustices haveplagued ethnic societies around the world. 33<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO has defined indigenous and tribal peoplesas those who have (a) traditi<strong>on</strong>al lifestyles,(b) culture, ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and way of lifethat is different from the other segments of thenati<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> (e.g., in their ways of makinga living, language and customs), and (c) theirown social organisati<strong>on</strong> and traditi<strong>on</strong>al customsand laws. Indigenous peoples are, furthermore,distinguished from tribal peoples by the fact thatthey live in historical c<strong>on</strong>tinuity in a certain area,or be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e others occupied or came to their area. 34<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> definiti<strong>on</strong> of ‘indigenous’ as provided by theUnited Nati<strong>on</strong>s shares features with that providedby ILO: it highlights the ‘historical c<strong>on</strong>tinuity ofthese peoples with pre-col<strong>on</strong>ial societies; theirstr<strong>on</strong>g attachment to their traditi<strong>on</strong>al territories;their distinct social, ec<strong>on</strong>omic and political instituti<strong>on</strong>sas well as distinct languages and beliefs;their n<strong>on</strong>-dominant positi<strong>on</strong> in nati<strong>on</strong>al societiesand their wish to identify themselves as differentfrom the rest of society.’ 35At the root of the poverty and social exclusi<strong>on</strong>facing ITPs everywhere is discriminati<strong>on</strong>. Whetherimplicitly or explicitly, ITPs have faced discriminati<strong>on</strong>aimed at wiping out their cultural identityBox 3 ILO’s C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Indigenous and Tribal Peoples1989 (No. 169)ILO adopted the Indigenous and Tribal Peoples C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>(No. 169) to include the fundamental c<strong>on</strong>cept thatthe ways of life of indigenous and tribal peoples shouldand will survive. It also stressed that these peoples andtheir traditi<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s must be closely involvedin the planning, design and implementati<strong>on</strong> of developmentpolicies that affect them. It sets the minimuminternati<strong>on</strong>al standards while opening the ground <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>higher standards in countries that can go further.C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> No. 169 adopts a general attitude of respect<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cultures and ways of life of indigenous andtribal peoples, placing emphasis <strong>on</strong> their right to ac<strong>on</strong>tinued existence and to development according totheir own priorities.It is a comprehensive instrument covering a range ofissues pertaining to indigenous and tribal peoples,including land rights, recruitment and c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s ofemployment, access to natural resources, social securityand health, educati<strong>on</strong> and means of communicati<strong>on</strong>,vocati<strong>on</strong>al training, c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of employment andcooperati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>tacts across borders.Protecti<strong>on</strong> is still the main objective but it is based <strong>on</strong>respect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenous and tribal people’s cultures, theirdistinct ways of life and their traditi<strong>on</strong>s and customs.It is also based <strong>on</strong> the belief that indigenous and tribalpeoples have the right to c<strong>on</strong>tinue to exist with theirown identities and the right to determine their own wayand pace of development.145


through a variety of legal instruments and policies.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y have ranged from outright exclusi<strong>on</strong> toinclusi<strong>on</strong> at very inferior c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> typical outcomes involved are dispossessi<strong>on</strong>of their traditi<strong>on</strong>al lands, relocati<strong>on</strong> withoutcompensati<strong>on</strong> and basic support services; underinvestmentin educati<strong>on</strong> and health; ill-adaptededucati<strong>on</strong>al systems and materials — all of whichtranslate, am<strong>on</strong>g others, into disadvantageousstatus in labour markets. ITPs expelled from theirancestral domains become seas<strong>on</strong>al, migrant,b<strong>on</strong>ded or home-based labourers; they are exposedto various <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of exploitati<strong>on</strong>. Discriminati<strong>on</strong>in wage is comm<strong>on</strong> practice and there ishigh incidence of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour. Unemployment,especially youth unemployment, is higher am<strong>on</strong>gITPs compared to the nati<strong>on</strong>al average. 36<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> challenge lies in how to improve living andworking c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s am<strong>on</strong>g ITPs so that they canc<strong>on</strong>tinue to exist as distinct peoples, if they wishto do so. Specific ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentof indigenous people have to be made. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO’sIndigenous and Tribal Peoples C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> (seeBox 3) provides guidance and strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalempowerment with respect not <strong>on</strong>ly to labourrights and protecti<strong>on</strong> of employment, but also toland and property rights.Special ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their legal empowerment aredem<strong>on</strong>strated in an ‘ethnic audit’ of 14 PovertyReducti<strong>on</strong> Strategy Papers (PRSPs) as well ascase studies of country processes in Bolivia,Cambodia, Camero<strong>on</strong>, Guatemala and Nepal. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>research clearly showed that while indigenouspeoples are disproporti<strong>on</strong>ately represented am<strong>on</strong>gthe poor, their needs and priorities are generallynot reflected in the strategies employed tocombat poverty.<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment of indigenous and tribalpeoples must address the structural causes oftheir disenfranchisement and social exclusi<strong>on</strong>through:• <strong>Legal</strong> frameworks that recognise individualand group rights.• Instituti<strong>on</strong>s and policies that respect and accommodatecultural diversity.• Organisati<strong>on</strong> and mobilisati<strong>on</strong> of indigenouspeople <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong> and political change. 37C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> vast majority of the working poor earn theirliving in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy where averageearnings are low, productivity is poor, workingc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are hazardous, and risks are high. Anyattempt to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulate policies and approaches<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy must understand itscharacteristics, including the deep segmentati<strong>on</strong>found in it. This secti<strong>on</strong> provided a global pictureof the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, highlighting its size,segmentati<strong>on</strong>, and the vulnerabilities of its particularsegments. Women dominate the most-disadvantagedcategories of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal work, 38 notablyindustrial outwork and home-based producti<strong>on</strong>. Itis also in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy that child labourand b<strong>on</strong>ded labour are most prevalent and mostdifficult to address. Indigenous and tribal peoplesare marginalized largely due to discriminati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir cultural identity is suppressed and they areexcluded from social services that should preparethem <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the labour market; furthermore, when atwork, they face many <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of discriminati<strong>on</strong>.Despite early predicti<strong>on</strong>s of its eventual demise,the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy has not <strong>on</strong>ly grownworldwide but also emerged in new guises andunexpected places. Though understood to becounter-cyclical, different segments of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy are seen to have differentcyclical patterns leading to different patternsof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> across countries. In virtually146


all cases, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy expands duringec<strong>on</strong>omic slumps or downturns, as expected.In some cases, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy expandsduring periods of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth has been accompanied by an increase inthe more dynamic micro-enterprise activities andsubc<strong>on</strong>tracted work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> larger supply chains especiallythose linked to the global ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Thus,the growing significance of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy— and its apparent endurance as a feature of thelabour market — leads us to examine how labourrights can be applicable to the workers found in itand what role legal empowerment of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malwork<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce can play in breaking the vicious cycleof low productivity and poverty.4. Poverty and LabourRights: a new departurePoverty: A market failure and a publicpolicy failure<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a broad c<strong>on</strong>sensus around the noti<strong>on</strong>that labour is not a commodity 39 and, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,that labour markets are different from other markets.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour market has a double functi<strong>on</strong>:it is a mechanism <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> both the creati<strong>on</strong> of newresources and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the distributi<strong>on</strong> of income andprosperity. While enterprises should be subject tocompetiti<strong>on</strong>, which means that some will succeedand grow while others will disappear, people orworkers have to be treated in a completely differentway. Public policies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> workers and theirfamilies have to be focused <strong>on</strong> inclusi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong> newopportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decent work and <strong>on</strong> shared prosperity(See Box 4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an elaborati<strong>on</strong> of the socialcase <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour regulati<strong>on</strong>).147In additi<strong>on</strong> to their intrinsic value <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the workingpoor, labour rights standards are fundamental toupholding the human rights obligati<strong>on</strong>s of statesand other ‘organs of society’ as set out in theUniversal Declarati<strong>on</strong> of Human Rights and manyother internati<strong>on</strong>al covenants, c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s, andtreaties, as well as set out in nati<strong>on</strong>al legislati<strong>on</strong>around the globe. From the perspective of this<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>, labour rights and regulati<strong>on</strong>s arealso fundamental to achieving legal employmentof the poor.Labour rights and labour standards have beenan issue <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> internati<strong>on</strong>al promoti<strong>on</strong> and regulati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> almost a hundred years. All countries,including the poorest countries, in principleprovide their work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce with labour rights. Labourlaws and labour protecti<strong>on</strong> models are traditi<strong>on</strong>allydesigned with the presumpti<strong>on</strong> of a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployer-employee relati<strong>on</strong>ship. This relati<strong>on</strong>-


Box 4 Social case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labourregulati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> social case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour market regulati<strong>on</strong>semanates, fi rst and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emost, from the principlethat labour is not a commodity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> distincti<strong>on</strong> liesin the human aspect of labour. As such, its behaviouris affected by the work envir<strong>on</strong>ment and by theincentives that are given. While machines operateaccording to technical specificati<strong>on</strong>s, labour has tobe motivated based <strong>on</strong> what they care about. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>yare c<strong>on</strong>tracted to per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m a certain job and are paidwhen they complete the job. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> completi<strong>on</strong> of thec<strong>on</strong>tract is not as straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward as it would be <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>n<strong>on</strong>-human means of producti<strong>on</strong> as this requiresa complex range of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> both sides andincentives to ensure compliance. 42ship has been the cornerst<strong>on</strong>e around whichlabour law, collective bargaining agreements andsocial security systems are framed. Whatever itsprecise definiti<strong>on</strong> in different nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>texts,the employment relati<strong>on</strong>ship has represented ‘auniversal noti<strong>on</strong> which creates a link between apers<strong>on</strong>, called the employee (frequently referredto as the ‘worker’) with another pers<strong>on</strong>, calledthe employer to whom she or he provides labouror services under certain c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in return <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>remunerati<strong>on</strong>.’ 40Despite the l<strong>on</strong>g-standing and wide-spreadcommitment to labour rights, a large majorityof workers are excluded from labour rights andsocial protecti<strong>on</strong>. Thus, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and povertyis not <strong>on</strong>ly a market failure, it is also a failure ofpublic policies. Several factors, in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ofhistoric traditi<strong>on</strong>s, structural failures and c<strong>on</strong>flictingpolitical interests, help explain the persistenceand growth of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality.• One explanati<strong>on</strong> is the history of labour lawand regulati<strong>on</strong>. Labour rights were historicallydesigned with the presumpti<strong>on</strong> of a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment relati<strong>on</strong>ship thus excluding thosewithout a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment relati<strong>on</strong>ship.• Another explanati<strong>on</strong> is a lack of c<strong>on</strong>fidencein laws and law en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement. Some politicalregimes have further undermined publicc<strong>on</strong>fidence due to poor governance, causingmany enterprises to operate in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy.• A third explanati<strong>on</strong> is a lack of public policyattenti<strong>on</strong>. Governments, employers, and workers— the three social partners in the ILOstandard-setting systems — have focused <strong>on</strong>the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal organisedlabour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment have been studied and discussedsince the 1970s. A first discussi<strong>on</strong> of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector took place at the Internati<strong>on</strong>alLabour C<strong>on</strong>ference in 1991 and subsequentlythe Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference reachedpolicy c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s regarding in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employmentin 2002. 41• Another factor is weak and poorly-designeden<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement mechanisms. Countries that haveimproved the design and reach of their en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementmechanisms to match the circumstancesof workers and units in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy have been able to reduce in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> relati<strong>on</strong>ship between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employmentand poverty had not, until recently, received theattenti<strong>on</strong> they deserve, much less reached the topof the development policy agenda. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> interestto bring about re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is quite new and the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mstrategies, discussed by the ILO, World Bank, theinternati<strong>on</strong>al trade uni<strong>on</strong> movement and others,and the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to develop feasible soluti<strong>on</strong>s bycountries with large in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omies, are stillin their early stages of development.148


A New Departure: Fundamental Principles andRights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>, the Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda, and<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Poor<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> recogniti<strong>on</strong> that productive employmentand decent work are key pathways to povertyreducti<strong>on</strong>, and that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality represents both amarket failure and a public policy failure, haveled to a reassessment of development strategiesof the 20 th century, including the ILO labourstandard strategy. Over the past decade, tripartitediscussi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> key related themes at the annualinternati<strong>on</strong>al labour c<strong>on</strong>ferences have c<strong>on</strong>tributedto this review process, as have the activism,scholarship, and policy analysis of other stakeholders.What has emerged from this rethinkingis an internati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>sensus around an agendaof fundamental principles and rights at work, alsoknown as core labour standards, decent work andlegal empowerment of the working poor in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> First Step: Fundamental Principles andRights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>: A first step in the developmentof new internati<strong>on</strong>al strategies to fight povertyand social injustice through labour rights was theestablishment by the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ferencein 1998 of a set of fundamental principlesand rights at work; they include:• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> right to freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> and collectivebargaining.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> eliminati<strong>on</strong> of all <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced or compulsorylabour.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> aboliti<strong>on</strong> of child labour.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> eliminati<strong>on</strong> of discriminati<strong>on</strong> in employmentand occupati<strong>on</strong>.Endorsed by the internati<strong>on</strong>al community, thesecore labour standards c<strong>on</strong>stitute a ‘minimumfloor’, necessary both <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the respect of fundamentalhuman rights and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the effective functi<strong>on</strong>ingof labour markets. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are applicable toall workers and ec<strong>on</strong>omic units.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Sec<strong>on</strong>d Step: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda: Asec<strong>on</strong>d step in the rethinking of traditi<strong>on</strong>al approacheswas the introducti<strong>on</strong> at the Internati<strong>on</strong>alLabour C<strong>on</strong>ference in 1999 of the Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>Agenda. Decent work is central to ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to fightpoverty. It is captured in four strategic objectives:fundamental principles and rights at work andinternati<strong>on</strong>al labour standards; employment andincome opportunities; social protecti<strong>on</strong> and socialsecurity; and social dialogue and tripartism.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se objectives hold <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all workers, women andmen, in both <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omies;engaged in wage employment or working <strong>on</strong> theirown account; and working <strong>on</strong> the streets or infields, factories, small workshops, or offices; intheir homes or in their neighbourhoods.<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment through labour rights is not<strong>on</strong>ly a means <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> preventing a race to the bottom.Such legal empowerment can also be designedto create c<strong>on</strong>fidence, to facilitate change and tomaintain cohesi<strong>on</strong>, as shown by many of the moreprosperous countries. Labour standards, collectiveagreements and social protecti<strong>on</strong> in thesecountries c<strong>on</strong>tribute to defining minimum levelsof income and productivity. In other words, effectiveapplicati<strong>on</strong> of labour standards can c<strong>on</strong>tributeto giving a positive incentive <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> enterprisesin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy to increase their productivityand incomes and to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal firms to extendlabour rights to all of their workers: both core andperipheral, both direct and c<strong>on</strong>tracted hires, upand down their supply chains.Labour standards are not <strong>on</strong>ly about the protecti<strong>on</strong>of worker rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also include promoti<strong>on</strong>almeasures, such as access to skillsupgrading, life l<strong>on</strong>g learning and productiveemployment.149


Box 5 ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s and Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s Pertinent tothe In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omyHuman capabilities andempowermentCore labour standards• Freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> andcollective bargaining(C87 and 98)• Equality (C 100 and 111)• Forced Labour (C 29 and 105)• Child Labour (C 138 and 182)(<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Indigenous and Tribal PeoplesC<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>, C 169, must also bementi<strong>on</strong>ed, in view of its provisi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>al measuresto eliminate prejudices and tocombat discriminati<strong>on</strong> and fullrealisati<strong>on</strong> of their rights.)Source: Anne Trebilcock 2004.Labour market policy frameworks<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> bettergovernanceEmployment policy• Employment Policy(C 122 and R169)• Job Creati<strong>on</strong> in SMEs(C 189)• Human Resource Development (C142 and R 195)Instituti<strong>on</strong>s of governance• LabourAdministrati<strong>on</strong> C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>(C 150)• Protecti<strong>on</strong> of Wages(C 95 and R 85)• Right to Organise and CollectiveBargaining (C 98 and 154)• C<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> (Industrial, Nati<strong>on</strong>al,and Tripartite (C 113 and 114)Protecti<strong>on</strong> of peopleSocial security instruments• Social Security (Minimum Standards)(C 102)• Indigenous and Tribal PeoplesC<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> (C 169)• Maternity Protecti<strong>on</strong> (C 183)Safety and health instruments• Occupati<strong>on</strong>al Safety and Health(C 155 and R 164)• Guarding of Machinery (C 119) and <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ingEnvir<strong>on</strong>ment (Air, Polluti<strong>on</strong>, Noise and Vibrati<strong>on</strong>;C 148)• Safety and Health in Agriculture(C 184)• Rural <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’ Organisati<strong>on</strong>(C 141)• Various safety and health c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s inspecific sectors such as mining,c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>, work involving asbestos andbenzene.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Third Step: Empower People in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy: This step was taken in 2002 when theInternati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference discussed andadopted a resoluti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> and theIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, representing a new departurein addressing the topic. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> new c<strong>on</strong>ceptualframework depicts a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum of producti<strong>on</strong>and employment relati<strong>on</strong>s. It does away with theidea that there are distinct <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal’sectors’ without direct links and instead stressesthat there are ‘linkages, grey areas and interdependenciesbetween <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal activities.’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> framework views <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises and workers as co-existing al<strong>on</strong>g ac<strong>on</strong>tinuum, with decent work deficits most seriousat the bottom, unprotected, unregulated, survivalistend, but also existing in some <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal jobsas well, and with increasingly decent c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>smoving up towards the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal protected end. Byhighlighting the dynamic linkages between <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maland in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal activities, the policy issue can morerealistically be framed: the issue is not whetherin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal units have direct tieswith the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy but whether those tiesare benign, exploitative or mutually beneficial.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy c<strong>on</strong>cern must enhance the positivelinkages and ensure that there is decent work allal<strong>on</strong>g the c<strong>on</strong>tinuum. 43150


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s stressed the need to ‘eliminatethe negative aspects of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality while at thesame time ensuring that opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> livelihoodand entrepreneurship are not destroyed,and promoting the protecti<strong>on</strong> and incorporati<strong>on</strong>of workers and ec<strong>on</strong>omic units in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy into the mainstream ec<strong>on</strong>omy.’ With aspecial focus <strong>on</strong> countries struggling with abjectpoverty and with a rapidly growing labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce,the ILO resoluti<strong>on</strong> urged that measures taken‘should not restrict opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> those whohave no other means of livelihood. However, itshould not be a job at any price or under any circumstances.’A clear challenge <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> follow-up is todem<strong>on</strong>strate how job quantity and quality can gotogether and how respect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> basic labour rightsmight promote productivity growth. A relatedchallenge is to ensure that activities targetingthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy do not lead to the growthof poor quality employment, but rather to theupgrading of working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>salso call <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an upward transiti<strong>on</strong>, not a downwardpull al<strong>on</strong>g the c<strong>on</strong>tinuum of decent work.Bey<strong>on</strong>d the four core labour standards there is arange of standards, including minimum wages,occupati<strong>on</strong>al safety and health, working hours,and maternity protecti<strong>on</strong>, which directly impactworking c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are determined nati<strong>on</strong>allyand their applicati<strong>on</strong> varies with the level ofdevelopment of the country and its capacity toen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce these standards. 44 One c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> of directrelevance to the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is the ILOHome <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>, adopted in 1996, whichworks to extend legal empowerment to homeworkers (industrial outworkers who work fromtheir homes), who are predominantly women.Compliance with these standards can be viewedas progressive, where different segments of thelabour market experience different degrees ofprotecti<strong>on</strong>. In reality, ‘the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal shades into thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal’ and people move between work opportunitieswith different degrees of protecti<strong>on</strong>. 45 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>goal is to progressively achieve compliance with abroader range of standards throughout the wholeec<strong>on</strong>omy, leading to gradual <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.It is instructive to highlight provisi<strong>on</strong>s in ILOC<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s and Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s that maybe applicable to the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seinternati<strong>on</strong>al labour standards provide guidanceto nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social policies, includinghow such policies can be applied to decentwork and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>sand Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s may be understoodunder the following broad objectives: (a) humancapabilities and empowerment, which relateto the core labour standards, (b) labour marketpolicy frameworks <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> better governance, and(c) protecti<strong>on</strong> of people. 46 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se standards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mthe backb<strong>on</strong>e of ILO’s Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> agenda, andcover not <strong>on</strong>ly the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector but also, mostimportantly, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. For it is in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy where decent work deficits arefound to be most challenging and disturbing.Towards a Global Social C<strong>on</strong>tractAs noted above, the internati<strong>on</strong>al communityhas endorsed three outcomes of the ILO’s internati<strong>on</strong>allabour c<strong>on</strong>ferences over the past decade,which, taken together, provide a strategicframework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> advancing the realisati<strong>on</strong> of labourrights, reducing poverty, and expanding equityworldwide. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1998 Declarati<strong>on</strong> of FundamentalPrinciples and Rights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>, the 1999Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda, and the 2002 Resoluti<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy have made significantc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s to what is now a widely-sharedcommitment to universally ensure a minimumfloor of fundamental labour rights; they have alsorecognised that the final objective should be the151


provisi<strong>on</strong> of full, productive, freely-chosen andprotected employment in a democratic c<strong>on</strong>text offreedom of voice, organisati<strong>on</strong> and social dialogue.Furthermore, the extensi<strong>on</strong> of this commitmentto include the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce providesa comprehensive framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> inclusi<strong>on</strong> of thoseam<strong>on</strong>g the poorer segments of the populati<strong>on</strong>who are employed but register significant deficitsin regard to decent work.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2005 World Summit of Heads of Statesstr<strong>on</strong>gly supported the goal of fair globalizati<strong>on</strong>and ‘resolved to make the goals of full andproductive employment and decent work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all,including <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women and young people, a centralobjective of our relevant nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>alpolicies as well as our nati<strong>on</strong>al developmentstrategies, including poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> strategies,as part of our ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to achieve the MillenniumDevelopment Goals.’ 47 This was followed by theUN Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Social Council (ECOSOC)2006 Ministerial Declarati<strong>on</strong>, which emphasisedfull and productive employment and decentwork <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all as an end in itself and as a meansto achieve the Millennium Development Goals(MDGs), including poverty eradicati<strong>on</strong>. On thisoccasi<strong>on</strong>, the multilateral system 48 was enjoinedto mainstream the goals of full and productiveemployment and decent work in all their policies,programmes and activities. 49<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> agenda has there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e been acceptedas a global goal and is no l<strong>on</strong>ger an ILOagenda al<strong>on</strong>e. Decent work has been declaredas a goal not <strong>on</strong>ly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal wage sector,but also <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. A decadel<strong>on</strong>gprocess of rethinking internati<strong>on</strong>al labourstandards has now led to an emerging globalsocial c<strong>on</strong>tract, a broad agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>empowerment.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Group <strong>on</strong> Labour Rights, in preparingthis chapter, saw an opportunity to move <strong>on</strong>estep further and provide additi<strong>on</strong>al elements tothis emerging global social c<strong>on</strong>tract. We suggestadvancing simultaneously <strong>on</strong> labour rights,job creati<strong>on</strong> and social protecti<strong>on</strong>, focusingparticularly <strong>on</strong> the working poor in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy.Labour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers: what is anachievable minimum fl oor?All workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy should becovered at least by a ‘minimum floor’ as c<strong>on</strong>tainedin the 1998 Declarati<strong>on</strong> of Principles and Rightsat <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>. This Declarati<strong>on</strong> established the applicati<strong>on</strong>of core human rights to the arena of labour orwork; included in its provisi<strong>on</strong>s are calls <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> no useof <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced or child labour, no discriminati<strong>on</strong>, andthe freedom of voice, organisati<strong>on</strong> and bargaining.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Declarati<strong>on</strong> also c<strong>on</strong>stitutes the foundati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementing other labour rights and providingenabling c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s to exercise them and, thus,achieving the objective of providing employmentopportunities while ensuring protecti<strong>on</strong>. 50 Thisminimum floor could include three additi<strong>on</strong>allabour standards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> determinants of working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s:hours of work, diseases and accidents atwork, and minimum wage. 51What we are proposing here — an enlarged minimumfloor — has already gained internati<strong>on</strong>alacceptance, notably during the last generati<strong>on</strong> offree trade agreements of the United States andcountries of Asia and Latin America. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> adopti<strong>on</strong>of such a minimum floor would ensure therights to rest, to health coverage of work-relatedrisks, and to fair remunerati<strong>on</strong> — all according tostandards established by nati<strong>on</strong>al legislati<strong>on</strong>. En<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementof such rights and provisi<strong>on</strong>s should berequired <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,independently of the size or <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of the ec<strong>on</strong>omicunit in which they work. This would justify rein-152


<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement and, eventually, a redesign of labourinspecti<strong>on</strong> instituti<strong>on</strong>s.For in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers outside <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises,full compliance of labour rights as establishedby nati<strong>on</strong>al legislati<strong>on</strong> needs to be en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced. Thisshould go bey<strong>on</strong>d the minimum floor, requiringeventually re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to the labour legislati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thefacilitati<strong>on</strong> of compliance. Advances in this directi<strong>on</strong>would lead to full achievement of the Decent<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> objectives.Un<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tunately, not all employment relati<strong>on</strong>shipsare explicit, where rights and obligati<strong>on</strong>scan be clearly identified. Many workers areemployed under diffuse employment relati<strong>on</strong>swhere the relati<strong>on</strong> is hidden or where there areproblems in the applicati<strong>on</strong> or interpretati<strong>on</strong> ofthe law. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> additi<strong>on</strong>al policies todetermine if an employment relati<strong>on</strong> exists and toclarify the resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> compliance am<strong>on</strong>gthose enterprises involving multi-parties. 52 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>latter kinds of arrangements are c<strong>on</strong>tinuing toexpand and are serving to decentralise the laboursystem in ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts, apparently, to reduce labourcosts. In the process, however, they are often bypassinglabour regulati<strong>on</strong>s and collective bargainingagreements and eroding the power of uni<strong>on</strong>s.Interpretati<strong>on</strong> of existing laws as well as newlegislati<strong>on</strong> will be needed to regulate these disguisedemployment arrangements, and to determinewhether an employment relati<strong>on</strong>ship existsand who is primarily resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> obligati<strong>on</strong>sto workers. This essential first step in movingtowards compliance should be followed by appropriatelyadapting labour laws and the labourinspecti<strong>on</strong> system. 53<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> situati<strong>on</strong> of workers in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprisesposes additi<strong>on</strong>al challenges, since the capacity ofmany in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises to absorb the cost ofcompliance is restricted by low productivity andincome. 54 As employment opportunities could bedestroyed in such cases, a strategy is needed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>increasing compliance and promoting progressiveen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement without legally adopting a dualsystem. An expanded minimum floor should, however,be en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced even in these enterprises, sincecost c<strong>on</strong>cern cannot be accepted as an argument<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-compliance given the nature of the rightsinvolved and the fact that compliance does notnecessarily involve significant costs.Most standards require abstinence fromdiscriminatory or unlawful behaviour ratherthan financial expenditure. A strategy could,however, recognise c<strong>on</strong>straints where they exist inadditi<strong>on</strong> to the obligati<strong>on</strong> to comply with a minimumfloor; basically, it should commit to gradualc<strong>on</strong>vergence to full compliance and to verificati<strong>on</strong>of progress towards this goal. This also requiresadapting the labour inspecti<strong>on</strong> procedures andpractices to move from sancti<strong>on</strong>s to training inthe early stages and to progressive compliance,as recommended by the ILO in a recent paper. 55A broad category that deserves special treatmentis that of home work (producti<strong>on</strong> or service workin a worker’s home) and domestic work (housecleaning, cooking <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> others). Included in thiscategory are significant numbers of workers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>might involve producing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> intermediaries insubc<strong>on</strong>tracting arrangements as well as selling orproducing directly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> employers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is also ac<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> of women and use of family workthat may involve children in these activities.Nati<strong>on</strong>al labour laws do not usually cover domesticworkers; they have no rights and little capacityto organise. Most are poor and experiencesignificant deficits of decent work. Employmentrelati<strong>on</strong>s, where they exist, justify the applicati<strong>on</strong>of rules covering other workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> (177) and a recommendati<strong>on</strong>(184) adopted by the Internati<strong>on</strong>al153


Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference in 1996, in recogniti<strong>on</strong> andsupport of home workers, calls <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their equaltreatment with other workers: in particular, itcalls <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> in organisati<strong>on</strong>sof their own choosing and protecti<strong>on</strong> againstdiscriminati<strong>on</strong>, minimum age <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> work, remunerati<strong>on</strong>and protecti<strong>on</strong> in safety and health at work,social security and maternity. This minimum floor<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> home workers, mandated in the 1996 C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>and Recommendati<strong>on</strong>, coincides with whatis proposed above <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all workers of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, with the additi<strong>on</strong> of social protecti<strong>on</strong>and maternity.Business and labour rights at work<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are, in additi<strong>on</strong>, a proporti<strong>on</strong> of independenthome workers that per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m a double role ofentrepreneur and worker and involve other familymembers in the producti<strong>on</strong> process. Independentworkers are also found bey<strong>on</strong>d those who work athome and c<strong>on</strong>stitute around half of employmentin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir identity is unclear,since they are both employers and workers, andtheir ways of organising should be open to theirpreferences. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir voice and their claims areusually directed against local governments andtheir behaviour in a highly competitive envir<strong>on</strong>mentis to operate in isolati<strong>on</strong> to other producersor workers in similar situati<strong>on</strong>s. In spite of thesecharacteristics, the minimum floor is relevant andcould enable these independents to organise,empowering them to exercise both their labourand business rights. On the latter, improvementsin the regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment and in processingwill result in increasing the opportunities to developbusinesses and in diminishing the barriersto grow. This should result in higher productivityand incomes.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference, in its 2007discussi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Sustainable Enterprises, 56 arguesthat ‘emphasis needs to be placed <strong>on</strong> the transiti<strong>on</strong>of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy operators to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy and ensuring that laws and regulati<strong>on</strong>scover all enterprises and workers.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO Resoluti<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> the Promoti<strong>on</strong> of Sustainable Enterprises,endorsed by employer, worker and governmentrepresentatives, argues that ‘poorly designedand unnecessary bureaucratic burdens <strong>on</strong> businesseslimit enterprise start-ups and the <strong>on</strong>goingoperati<strong>on</strong>s of existing companies, and leadto in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, corrupti<strong>on</strong> and efficiency costs.’Well-designed transparent, accountable and wellcommunicatedregulati<strong>on</strong>s, including those thatuphold labour and envir<strong>on</strong>mental standards, aregood <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> markets and society. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y facilitate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>and boost systemic competitiveness.Regulatory re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and the removal of businessc<strong>on</strong>tracts should not undermine such standards.Social protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> extensi<strong>on</strong> of social protecti<strong>on</strong> — health andpensi<strong>on</strong>s, as well as maternity — to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malworkers requires a strategy that c<strong>on</strong>siders differentopti<strong>on</strong>s, from expanding coverage of existingsystems to the development of new mechanismsby the excluded, through pooling, of resources orinsurances. Alternatives should be c<strong>on</strong>sidered,while examples of different schemes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the provisi<strong>on</strong>of protecti<strong>on</strong> need to be evaluated. Indiarecently introduced a bill to regulate employmentand service c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of unorganised workersand to provide <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their safety, social security,health and welfare and introduced a WelfareFund financed by government and registeredemployers with this purpose. 57 In the Philippines,the Statutory Social Security system andthe health insurance plans have increased theircoverage through voluntary schemes open to selfemployedworkers. 58From a systemic perspective, these rights should154


e granted to people as citizens rather than asworkers, and they should be awarded <strong>on</strong> theprinciple of universality. This has already been reflectedin Latin America, where some ‘traditi<strong>on</strong>almodels’ have been redesigned, by the additi<strong>on</strong>of a publicly-financed ‘solidarity pillar’ to privatec<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> pensi<strong>on</strong> systems. In its recently publishedreport <strong>on</strong> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality in Latin America, 59the World Bank fully supports this change <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>both health and pensi<strong>on</strong> coverage. In the caseof health care, shocks that go uncovered imposesignificant costs to society. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, there isa case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> providing minimum essential healthcoverage, de-linked from the labour c<strong>on</strong>tract andfinanced through general taxati<strong>on</strong>. Similarly, inthe case of insufficient incomes in old age, thereare social costs involved that justify minimumincome support not linked to the labour c<strong>on</strong>tract.Chile, which pi<strong>on</strong>eered the privatisati<strong>on</strong> of thepensi<strong>on</strong> and health systems, is taking the lead inintroducing a n<strong>on</strong>-c<strong>on</strong>tributory pillar that guaranteesa solidarity pensi<strong>on</strong> to all citizens above 65years old who receive a pensi<strong>on</strong> of 50 percent ofthe minimum wage. It will be universally granted,but efficiency is ensured by gradually reducingthe subsidy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> those who receive other pensi<strong>on</strong>s,thus reducing the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public fundsand providing incentives to c<strong>on</strong>tribute to thesystem. In fact, the resulting model establishesa mid-way <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-c<strong>on</strong>tributory pensi<strong>on</strong>s, since itis universal <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all citizens, but it recovers partlythe fiscal c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> from high-income pensi<strong>on</strong>ers.Bolivia is the <strong>on</strong>ly country in Latin Americathat has introduced a universal n<strong>on</strong>-c<strong>on</strong>tributorypensi<strong>on</strong> (BONOSOL) and Brazil has a similarsystem <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rural workers (FUNRURAL). 60 Healthis covered to a larger extent than pensi<strong>on</strong>s andreaches universality by a combinati<strong>on</strong> of differentsystems: a social insurance system in CostaRica that covers c<strong>on</strong>tributors and n<strong>on</strong>-c<strong>on</strong>tributors;a public-funded system in Cuba, and a mixof public instituti<strong>on</strong>s, social security and privateinsurances in Uruguay, Brazil and Chile, am<strong>on</strong>gothers. Chile has strengthened access to publichealth <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all citizens by introducing an attenti<strong>on</strong>guarantee of 56 basic pathologies (AUGE) inadditi<strong>on</strong> to the existing nati<strong>on</strong>al health insurance(FONASA).De-linking health and pensi<strong>on</strong> coverage fromthe labour market would create opportunitiesto increase employment and improve businesses,while guaranteeing security. It will helpdecrease the existing protecti<strong>on</strong> deficits but it willrequire sound fiscal policies and, particularly, theadequate funding of decent health and pensi<strong>on</strong>scoverage. A similar approach should be used inthe case of child care and maternity given thepotential effect, respectively, <strong>on</strong> the early developmentof cognitive abilities in children and theparticipati<strong>on</strong> of women, particularly those frompoor households, in the labour market.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role and Limitati<strong>on</strong>s of Voluntary Codes ofC<strong>on</strong>ductMultinati<strong>on</strong>al corporati<strong>on</strong>s and n<strong>on</strong>-governmentorganisati<strong>on</strong>s have also taken <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward the corelabour standards and the decent work agenda byestablishing voluntary codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct, involvingin some cases subc<strong>on</strong>tractors and outworkers.Codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct c<strong>on</strong>stitute a strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>motivating improvements in the per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>manceof multinati<strong>on</strong>al corporati<strong>on</strong>s. Am<strong>on</strong>g the manyimportant initiatives are the Fair Labour Associati<strong>on</strong>,SA8000, the Clean Clothes CampaignFoundati<strong>on</strong> and the Ethical Trading Initiative.While the codes advanced through these programmesvary, most of them tend to be based <strong>on</strong>ILO’s core standards, particularly the prohibiti<strong>on</strong>of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour, child labour, and discriminati<strong>on</strong>in the workplace. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se organisati<strong>on</strong>s take155


different paths to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement, with some takinga centralised approach in overseeing and c<strong>on</strong>trollingpayments <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>itoring, while others followa ‘c<strong>on</strong>sulting firm approach’ which allows companiesto choose and pay <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their own m<strong>on</strong>itors.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a need to move towards unified codes inthe interest of promoting good governance in thebusiness sector.Labour Rights, Social Protecti<strong>on</strong>, EmploymentCreati<strong>on</strong>: trade-offs or complementarities?<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> emerging global social c<strong>on</strong>tract shouldinclude the promoti<strong>on</strong> of more and better employmentopportunities and aim to reduce the existinggaps in protecti<strong>on</strong>, particularly c<strong>on</strong>centratedin poorer populati<strong>on</strong>. It has to open opportunitiesas well as to provide protecti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are tradeoffsinvolved, but there are also str<strong>on</strong>g complementarities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> experience accumulated duringthe last decades could c<strong>on</strong>tribute to enhance thelatter effects, without ignoring the less<strong>on</strong>s learntto diminish unnecessary costs introduced by illdesignedpolicies. Security provides incentives<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> learning and innovati<strong>on</strong> and both are requirements<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> growth and employment creati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reis also need to facilitate adaptati<strong>on</strong> of firms to thenew competitive c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, and this is particularlyrelevant in matters involving labour c<strong>on</strong>tractsand regulati<strong>on</strong>s.One of the less<strong>on</strong>s learnt is that the prescripti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> flexibility, through the introducti<strong>on</strong> of temporaryor atypical labour c<strong>on</strong>tracts, has serious drawbacks, affecting more than the lives of workersand their families. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rigidity of the permanentc<strong>on</strong>tract and, particularly, the costs involved interminating this type of c<strong>on</strong>tract, could c<strong>on</strong>stitutea barrier in times of adjustment. On the otherhand, such c<strong>on</strong>tracts also provide a simple way ofprotecti<strong>on</strong> in countries where other mechanisms,like unemployment insurance, do not exist or arevery limited. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> erosi<strong>on</strong> of the permanent c<strong>on</strong>tractcan be changed by going back to a modifiedversi<strong>on</strong>; <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, by introducing l<strong>on</strong>ger trialperiods, reducing or increasing the severancepayments in case of terminati<strong>on</strong> of employment,etc. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> availability of temporary and fixed-termc<strong>on</strong>tracts will still be needed, particularly to openwider opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> those more affected byunemployment and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> those who wish to rec<strong>on</strong>cileeducati<strong>on</strong> or house-family care resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities.At the same time, temporary or fixed-termjobs should not replace permanent jobs and thelimits of their use should be established throughc<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> and dialogue.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> of hidden employmentrelati<strong>on</strong>s or those without c<strong>on</strong>tracts will provideidentity to the affected workers and c<strong>on</strong>stituteenabling c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> them to exercise theirlabour rights, particularly labour and socialprotecti<strong>on</strong>. At the same time, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> ofemployment relati<strong>on</strong>s, even if gradually achieved,opens opportunities and provides incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>improving business management. A culturalchange in the management of micro-enterprisesand, particularly, of family businesses is induced,since compliance with labour obligati<strong>on</strong>s requiresthe introducti<strong>on</strong> of accountancy and cost benefitsanalysis to ensure viability of the enterprise. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>right of associati<strong>on</strong> is also c<strong>on</strong>ducive to developingalliances between producers, thus rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cingtheir voice and their ability to negotiate with localauthorities; it is also enabling <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> potential pricereducti<strong>on</strong> of their inputs and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> easier accessto c<strong>on</strong>centrated markets. This also representsa major cultural change since it means shiftingfrom individualistic to collective behaviour. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>rehas been internati<strong>on</strong>al tripartite c<strong>on</strong>sensus <strong>on</strong> theneed to combat disguised employment relati<strong>on</strong>ships.Nati<strong>on</strong>al policy could serve to ensure effectiveprotecti<strong>on</strong> to workers especially affected by156


uncertainty as to the existence of an employmentrelati<strong>on</strong>ship (workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example). 61C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>sThis review of development strategies and ofinternati<strong>on</strong>al labour standard setting showsthat there is a growing political understandingof the fundamental importance of employmentand work c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fight against poverty.It also shows that there is a new departure inthe internati<strong>on</strong>al community regarding labourrights and that work in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omynow is addressed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> three elements of this newdeparture — Fundamental Principles and Rightsat <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>, the Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda and the rightsin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy — are now supported bya broad coaliti<strong>on</strong> of governments, internati<strong>on</strong>alorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, trade uni<strong>on</strong>s and employers andn<strong>on</strong>-governmental organisati<strong>on</strong>s.5. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omics ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and the debate<strong>on</strong> Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is now a broad recogniti<strong>on</strong> of a decent workdeficit in the global labour market - from the absenceof social protecti<strong>on</strong> to the absence of basicrights at work. A key ec<strong>on</strong>omic indicator of thatdeficit, as explained by the ILO World Employmentreport of 2004/2005, is whether men andwomen can earn enough from their work to liftthemselves and their families out of poverty. Forthe estimated 500 milli<strong>on</strong> working poor who livein households with daily incomes of less thanUS$1 per capita, the answer is ‘no’. In their case,it is not the absence of ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity that isthe source of their poverty, but the nature of theirec<strong>on</strong>omic activities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> link between work of lowquality or productivity and poverty is starkly clear:if people were able to earn more from their work,then poverty would decline. Thus, it is not justany work per se which can raise individuals out ofpoverty; but rather productive and decent work.Taking this view as point of departure, the purposeof this secti<strong>on</strong> is to provide a brief overviewof the role of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>s in ec<strong>on</strong>omic per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance.We examine, firstly, some broad crosscountryevidence about the impact of labourregulati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> growth and employment, makingreferences to a number of individual countrystudies. We then proceed to what we would argueis an important addendum to reinterpretingprior assumpti<strong>on</strong>s regarding the nature, role andimpact of labour market regulati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the workingpoor of the world. Our recommendati<strong>on</strong>s arepresented at the end of this secti<strong>on</strong>.157


Table 1 Mean Measures of Regulati<strong>on</strong>, by Income LevelArea of Regulati<strong>on</strong>LowIncome LMI UMIHI - n<strong>on</strong>OECDHI -OECDTotalRigidity of Hiring 44.28 33.68 29.91 27.00 20.60 34.33Rigidity of Hours 47.60 39.64 40.57 45.22 32.00 42.40Rigidity of Firing 40.00 33.04 33.43 27.39 14.00 33.26Aggreg. Employment Index 43.96 35.45 34.64 33.20 22.20 36.66Hiring Costs 12.40 16.01 17.31 21.43 10.17 15.62Firing Costs 65.32 50.91 44.63 31.32 54.64 51.34Source: Doing Business, 2006 and authors’ own calculati<strong>on</strong>s1. ‘LMI’ refers to Lower Middle Income countries; UMI to Upper Middle Income countries and HI to High Income ec<strong>on</strong>omies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are standard classificati<strong>on</strong>sdrawn from the World Bank’s World Development Report (2005).2. All indices are normalised to 100, with the italicised, composite indices the arithmetic mean of the preceding sub-indices.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic impact of LabourRegulati<strong>on</strong>: an overview of key resultsThis secti<strong>on</strong> provides an overview of some ofthe key measures and results from the InvestmentClimate Assessment (ICA) surveys and theDoing Business Survey (DBS) both run underthe auspices of the World Bank with a focus <strong>on</strong>summary measures of labour market regulati<strong>on</strong>and worker protecti<strong>on</strong>. 62 In turn, we raise somecauti<strong>on</strong> about the interpretative value and policyrelevance of these results.Most studies of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> are based<strong>on</strong> the assumpti<strong>on</strong> that such regulati<strong>on</strong>sare, in <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m or another, obstacles to businessoperati<strong>on</strong>, and hence, to productivity and prosperity.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se studies rarely address the intrinsic valueof regulati<strong>on</strong>s, or the perceived need or politicalec<strong>on</strong>omic circumstances that gave rise to the regulati<strong>on</strong>sin the first place. 63 A first questi<strong>on</strong> is whatrole labour regulati<strong>on</strong>s play relative to other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msof regulati<strong>on</strong> in hindering the growth of firms. Thisquesti<strong>on</strong> was addressed recently in an ICA survey.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> of this survey was that the topten most frequently reported obstacles to growingbusiness operati<strong>on</strong> were: policy uncertainty, macroinstability, tax rates, corrupti<strong>on</strong>, cost and access tofinance, crime, regulati<strong>on</strong> and tax administrati<strong>on</strong>,skills, court and legal systems, and electricity.Labour regulati<strong>on</strong> came in at eleventh place,reported by 16 percent of the resp<strong>on</strong>dents. Morepointed evidence from the Business EnterpriseSurvey Unit of the World Bank, which includesthe ICA surveys, suggests that firms around theworld do not necessarily view labour regulati<strong>on</strong>sas a dominant determinant of, nor obstacles to,growing their businesses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> evidence suggeststhat less than six percent of all firms, irrespectiveof size, view labour regulati<strong>on</strong>s as a ‘severe’or ‘major’ obstacle to business expansi<strong>on</strong>. Thisfigure is between 2.5 and 5.5 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> lowincome, lower middle-income and upper middleincomeec<strong>on</strong>omies. In the case of high-income(OECD) ec<strong>on</strong>omies, the estimate is about 10.5percent (World Bank, 2007). No significantlydifferent estimates are derived by size of theenterprise. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, and notwithstanding theiroverall limited relevance to business growth, thepercepti<strong>on</strong> of the relevance of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>sto business growth increases with the level ofdevelopment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the DBS158


surveys discussed below, the ICA surveys indicatethat labour regulati<strong>on</strong>s appear to be of even morelimited relevance to low-income countriesIn c<strong>on</strong>trast to the ICA surveys, the DBS is focused<strong>on</strong> a detailed assessment of the regulatoryenvir<strong>on</strong>ment in individual ec<strong>on</strong>omies. It hasan extensive labour regulati<strong>on</strong> module, whichis based very closely <strong>on</strong> the methodology of theBotero et al (2004) study. 64 In additi<strong>on</strong>, the DBSis the most recent, and indeed, possibly the mostwidely used measure of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> andworker protecti<strong>on</strong> within an internati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text.Hence, despite some reservati<strong>on</strong>s expressedregarding the DBS, it c<strong>on</strong>tinues to be a centralin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> base <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policymakers and investorsalike. For this reas<strong>on</strong>, our working group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Chapter 3 of this report has made review of themethodology of the DBS and the debate <strong>on</strong> theDBS the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> table above presents a snapshot of thekey measures available to the public user,from the dataset. We present the data by countryincome level. All measures are c<strong>on</strong>verted to anindex ranging between 0 and 100. Values closerto 100 indicate higher levels of rigidity or protecti<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘difficulty-of-hiring’ index measuresrestricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> part-time and temporary c<strong>on</strong>tracts,together with the wages of trainees relative toworker value-added. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rigidity of hours measuresthe various restricti<strong>on</strong>s around weekend, Sundaypublic holiday work, as well as limits <strong>on</strong> overtime,and so <strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘firing’ index examines specificredundancy clauses within the relevant legislati<strong>on</strong>in detail. What the DBS refers to as hiring costs,are in effect social protecti<strong>on</strong> costs, measuring allsocial security and health costs associated withhiring a worker. Finally, the cost of firing, measuresthe costs of terminating the employment ofan individual in terms of legislated notice-periodrequirements, severance pay, and so <strong>on</strong>.From the aggregate cross-country data, there isan interesting bifurcati<strong>on</strong> in the regulati<strong>on</strong> andprotecti<strong>on</strong> measures. Hence, the data indicatethat the highest measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> any area of regulati<strong>on</strong>relating to rigidity in hiring, firing and hoursof work are found in low income ec<strong>on</strong>omies,with the lowest level of employment regulati<strong>on</strong>am<strong>on</strong>gst high income OECD ec<strong>on</strong>omies. In additi<strong>on</strong>,the data show that firing costs are also thehighest am<strong>on</strong>gst low income countries, althoughnotably hiring costs are the highest in n<strong>on</strong>-OECDhigh income ec<strong>on</strong>omies.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>sequences of Labour Market Regulati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are two important questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> policy issuesthat are of relevance to the debate aroundlabour regulati<strong>on</strong> and worker protecti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>first revolves around the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of labourregulati<strong>on</strong>, in all its different manifestati<strong>on</strong>s, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth: do we find evidence that labourmarket regulati<strong>on</strong> hinders ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth? <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>sec<strong>on</strong>d issue is related, but more c<strong>on</strong>cerned withthe specific outcomes in the labour market, as ac<strong>on</strong>sequence of this regulatory regime: does theevidence suggest <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, that higher levelsof labour regulati<strong>on</strong> are correlated with higherrates of youth unemployment, larger in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment and so <strong>on</strong>?A number of studies suggest that regulati<strong>on</strong>in general, and labour regulati<strong>on</strong> in particular,is negatively and significantly associated withgrowth in per capita GDP (Loayza et al, 2006;Forteza and Rama, 2001; Heckman and Pagés,2003). On the other hand, Botero et al (2004)find that ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no evidence that employmentlaws or collective relati<strong>on</strong>s laws vary with thelevel of ec<strong>on</strong>omic development.’ 65 Loayza et alshow that the effect of regulati<strong>on</strong> is graduallymitigated as governance — and thus regulatoryquality — improves.159


However, a more detailed examinati<strong>on</strong> of theabove literature suggests that the crosscountrygrowth regressi<strong>on</strong>s often reflect either <strong>on</strong>the specific comp<strong>on</strong>ents of the labour regulatoryregime that may be hindering growth, or indeedrepresent the entire gamut of labour legislati<strong>on</strong>as <strong>on</strong>e index. Both these approaches and subsequentresults suggest that there is a heterogeneityin the labour regulatory regime that needs tobe grasped, and furthermore that this heterogeneitycan have a differential impact <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth. For example, Forteza and Rama (2001)find in <strong>on</strong>e of their set of results, that over theperiod 1970-86, the number of ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>sratified is insignificantly related to GDP growth,but that the minimum wage indicator is negativeand significant. Loayza et al (2006), in turn, finda significant and negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship betweenec<strong>on</strong>omic growth and the labour regulati<strong>on</strong> index,but this index is represented as an aggregatemeasure, and is not expanded into the comp<strong>on</strong>entsnoted in Table 1.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> evidence <strong>on</strong> the impact of the labour regulatoryregime <strong>on</strong> specific labour market indicators,in additi<strong>on</strong>, suggests similar outcomes andc<strong>on</strong>sequent c<strong>on</strong>cerns. Hence higher levels oflabour regulati<strong>on</strong> appear to be significantly associatedwith a larger in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, higherin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment, reduced male participati<strong>on</strong>rates and higher unemployment rates particularlyam<strong>on</strong>gst the youth (Botero et al. 2004;Loayza et al. 2006; Lazear 1990). However,<strong>on</strong>ce again, these results are either too aggregatedin their measure of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>, orindeed, do reflect <strong>on</strong> the heterogeneous impact oflabour regulati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> these labour market indicators.Specifically, then, it is not clear whetherall comp<strong>on</strong>ents of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> and workerprotecti<strong>on</strong> encourage growth of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment,or some comp<strong>on</strong>ents do so more thanothers. This would seem to be a critical avenueof enquiry — in order to better assist the currentpolicy debate. In additi<strong>on</strong>, where such specificityis isolated, as in the Botero et al (2004) study,<strong>on</strong>e finds that certain comp<strong>on</strong>ents of the labourregime are more important than others in shapinglabour market outcomes. Hence, protective collectiverelati<strong>on</strong>s laws, but no other comp<strong>on</strong>ents ofthe labour regulatory architecture, are shown tobe associated with a larger in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Across-country growth regressi<strong>on</strong> analysis(using the ordinary least squares approach)serves to illustrate the problem of aggregatingacross indices to arrive at firm c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s. Ifsuch a regressi<strong>on</strong> is run <strong>on</strong> the DBS 2006 results,and simply includes most of the individualregulati<strong>on</strong> indices — rather than the compositemeasures often utilised - the regulatory effectsincluding those <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the labour market aremuted. Hence, of the individual labour regulatorymeasures in this admittedly very simplisticspecificati<strong>on</strong>, two of the five (hiring costs andhours rigidity) are significant at the five percentlevel. Notably however, the signs <strong>on</strong> both thesecoefficients are positive, indicating, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example,that higher hiring costs (and hours of rigidity) areassociated with higher GNI per capita ec<strong>on</strong>omies.This does not mean, however, that regulati<strong>on</strong> ingeneral and labour regulati<strong>on</strong> in particular, arenot important in the growth debate. Instead, itdoes suggest some cauti<strong>on</strong> in our interpretati<strong>on</strong>of the published results and, more importantly,their translati<strong>on</strong> into country-level policy interventi<strong>on</strong>swithout due c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> both to theheterogeneity in the regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment, andto country-specific c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.Two additi<strong>on</strong>al caveats to the debate relating tothe impact of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> are worth noting.Firstly, that the absolute impact of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>may, even when using composite measures,160


e lower than that created by other regulatoryindices. Hence, Loayza et al (2006) note thatwhile GDP growth declines by 0.42 percentagepoints <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> every <strong>on</strong>e standard deviati<strong>on</strong> increasein an ec<strong>on</strong>omy’s (composite) labour regulati<strong>on</strong> index,this estimate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> product market regulati<strong>on</strong>sis over four times as large, at 1.86 percentagepoints. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fact is that the negative correlati<strong>on</strong>of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> with average income is notstatistically significant.Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, (and again drawing <strong>on</strong> Loayza et al[2006]), good governance and the quality of regulati<strong>on</strong>s,noted below, do make a difference. Hence,specificati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>trolling <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> quality of regulati<strong>on</strong>,do appear to erode some of the negative impact oflabour and product market regulati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> growth.For labour market regulati<strong>on</strong>s, the threshold ofgovernance quality required is relatively low andcomparable to Ireland and Portugal. For productmarket regulati<strong>on</strong>s, the threshold is quite high andcomparable to the quality of governance in Switzerland,United States and England. Hence, thenoti<strong>on</strong> that labour regulati<strong>on</strong>s can and do interactwith the quality of their applicati<strong>on</strong> in explaininggrowth outcomes and does so in a n<strong>on</strong>-linear manner,is a nuance that should not be lost.Thirdly, <strong>on</strong>e of the indicators in the DBS, the ‘employingworkers indicator’ (EWI), is now subjectto a debate between the ILO and the World Bank.While the Bank recently has revised its policy torequire that its c<strong>on</strong>tractors respect core labourstandards, the ILO claims that recommendati<strong>on</strong>sbased <strong>on</strong> EWI are c<strong>on</strong>trary to that policy. In a reviewof the EWI the ILO states that the index doesnot take into account the reas<strong>on</strong>s of labour legislati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO in fact argues that ‘the narrow andlimited methodological foundati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the EWI areinsufficient and possibly damaging as a guide topolicy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong>.’ 66On the general aspect of regulati<strong>on</strong> and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malitysome studies focus <strong>on</strong> the voluntary aspectsof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality. 67 By avoiding taxes and regulatoryobligati<strong>on</strong>s, it is believed that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal companiesgain a substantial cost advantage that allowsthem to stay in business despite their small scaleand low productivity. More productive, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malcompanies are prevented from gaining marketshare. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> result is slower ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth andjob creati<strong>on</strong>. 68<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Organisati<strong>on</strong> of Employers(IOE) 69 describes the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy as‘largely negative,’ trapping individuals and enterprisesin a spiral of low productivity and poverty.For governments it entails the loss of revenue,‘and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> workers it can mean inferior workingc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, job insecurity, lack of access to statebenefits and social security.’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Impact of Labour Market Regulati<strong>on</strong>: CountryStudiesA recent OECD 70 study found that making firingmore expensive <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> older workers will protectthem against dismissal while severance paymentsallow workers to smooth c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> duringunemployment periods. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also increase theincentive <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> l<strong>on</strong>ger-lasting employment relati<strong>on</strong>ships,which may increase worker satisfacti<strong>on</strong>and productivity. At the aggregate level, morestable employment-relati<strong>on</strong>s foster technologicalprogress and skill upgrading 71 and, in an argumentfrequently used in Latin America, workerprotecti<strong>on</strong>, they correct potential power asymmetriesbetween employees and firms. 72Yet, various studies have shown that firing costscan lead to greater in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y increase costsby <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing firms to keep n<strong>on</strong>-productive workersin the firm, or to remain overstaffed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> significantperiods of time. Thus it makes it more difficult<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> firms to fire, but also to hire. In developed161


countries this translates into unemployment, andin Latin America (which, however, is often overregulated),it translates into lower <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal labourdemand and larger in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality. For instance:• A recent study that explicitly models theimpact of firing costs over labour demand inPeru shows that an increase in expected severancepayments has a negative correlati<strong>on</strong> with<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal labour demand. 73• Kugler et al. 74 found that in Spain a reducti<strong>on</strong>in payroll taxes and firing costs increased thedemand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> permanent workers.• Acemoglu and Angrist, in an interesting studyabout the effects of the American DisabilityAct, found that outlawing the firing of disabledworkers actually reduced labour demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>disabled workers, precisely the opposite effectthat the law intended. 75<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> recent work <strong>on</strong> the Indian labour regulatoryregime (Besley and Burgess, 2004; Ahsan andPagés 2007) suggests that the clauses linked tofirm size within the industrial disputes regulatoryarchitecture may have had a deleterious impact<strong>on</strong> the growth of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy’s manufacturingindustry (Ahmed and Devarajan, 2007). However,<strong>on</strong>ce again, these c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s are incomplete:Firstly, the Indian experience indicates that whilethe regulati<strong>on</strong>s are a part of the problem, in somecases the operati<strong>on</strong>al and logistical inefficienciesas well complexities associated with settlingdisputes (Ahmed and Devarajan, 2007) are significantin explaining the lack of expansi<strong>on</strong> withinmanufacturing. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, while amending partsof the regulatory framework is necessary it is alsotrue that active labour market programmes andpolicies, such as those recommended by the ILO<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> India, must be part of any attempt at encouragingsecure employment creati<strong>on</strong> and reducingpoverty levels.Towards a More NuancedUnderstanding of Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> above has suggested that, <strong>on</strong> the basis ofthe assembled evidence, the labour regulatoryenvir<strong>on</strong>ment is important in the debate aroundoutput expansi<strong>on</strong> and employment growth indomestic ec<strong>on</strong>omies. This fact however, shouldnot translate into too blunt an interpretati<strong>on</strong>,and c<strong>on</strong>sequent policy advice, <strong>on</strong> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming thelabour legislative envir<strong>on</strong>ment at the individualcountry level.Some caveats need to be introduced here if amore in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med debate around labour regulati<strong>on</strong>and policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in the developing world is toensue. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y may help to ensure progress in dealingappropriately and intelligibly with the labourmarket in the event that policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m packagesare tabled at country level. Perhaps ec<strong>on</strong>omists,who are often at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>efr<strong>on</strong>t of such re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mprocesses, should understand the most importantof these cauti<strong>on</strong>ary notes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> caveat is thatlabour regulati<strong>on</strong> as a re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m issue, is not to beviewed as a binary variable. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> choice withinany policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m package in most ec<strong>on</strong>omiesis never between no labour regulati<strong>on</strong> at all andcomplete, comprehensive legislati<strong>on</strong>. Unduefocus by ec<strong>on</strong>omists <strong>on</strong> extreme deregulati<strong>on</strong>of the labour market often results in no re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mat all. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> noti<strong>on</strong> that a labour market, like anyproduct market, needs to be as deregulated as faras is theoretically possible, can result in c<strong>on</strong>tentiousand not very productive policy debates. Inthe c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s of the study <strong>on</strong> Impact of Regulati<strong>on</strong>and Growth and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, Loayza et al.bring a similar message. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y emphasise thattheir study ‘does not intend to assess the impactof regulati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> social goals that could be bey<strong>on</strong>dthe strict sphere of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth — broadgoals such as social equity and peace, or narrow<strong>on</strong>es as worker safety, envir<strong>on</strong>mental c<strong>on</strong>serva-162


ti<strong>on</strong>, and civil security, which typically motivatesspecific regulati<strong>on</strong>s. Thus, our c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> therole of regulati<strong>on</strong> must necessarily be evaluatedin a more comprehensive c<strong>on</strong>text be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e drawingdefinitive social welfare implicati<strong>on</strong>s.’One specific manifestati<strong>on</strong> of this problematicparadigm lies in the area of uni<strong>on</strong> power.For ec<strong>on</strong>omists, this is a standard sub-measure ofrigidity in the labour market. Within the Botero etal study (2004), <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, it is captured underthe collective rights index. However, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> many legalexperts the right to join a uni<strong>on</strong> and the freedomof associati<strong>on</strong> are viewed as universal rightsissues and not by any means as matters touching<strong>on</strong> labour market regulati<strong>on</strong>. Such experts wouldalso view positively the idea that the greater thenumber of uni<strong>on</strong>ised individuals in a society thestr<strong>on</strong>ger the indicati<strong>on</strong> of a thriving democraticsociety with enshrined individual rights andinterests. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> noti<strong>on</strong> that uni<strong>on</strong> membership issomehow coupled with labour market rigidity isanathema to a significant proporti<strong>on</strong> of the legalcommunity. Indeed, policy c<strong>on</strong>sistency is requiredwhen stressing the importance of democracyand good governance to ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth <strong>on</strong>the <strong>on</strong>e hand, while reflecting <strong>on</strong> rigidity inducedby high levels of uni<strong>on</strong> power <strong>on</strong> the other.Interpretati<strong>on</strong> of Regulati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> standard measures of regulati<strong>on</strong> found in theDBS are, as noted above, numeric c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong>s ofcountry-level legislative provisi<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> DBS doesnot proclaim to do any more than this. However,it is worth reiterating the importance of how suchlegislati<strong>on</strong> is interpreted by both the courts of lawand the relevant instituti<strong>on</strong>s of authority (such as,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> bodies). Legislativeprovisi<strong>on</strong>s are more often than not, subject tointerpretati<strong>on</strong> by the relevant legal authority. Howjudges, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, interpret the noti<strong>on</strong> of ‘fairdismissal’ falls to a variety of different variablesincluding the subjective opini<strong>on</strong> of the judge; themerits of the particular case; the evoluti<strong>on</strong> of jurisprudence<strong>on</strong> relevant issues raised in the case;the resources available to the parties and so <strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> simultaneous impact of these variables wouldthere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e then lead to a specific interpretati<strong>on</strong> ofthe law. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> outcome, as a c<strong>on</strong>sequence of thesefactors, may be an over-regulati<strong>on</strong> or indeedunder-regulati<strong>on</strong> of specific labour market activitiessuch as reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> dismissal; unfair labourpractices; probati<strong>on</strong> rights and so <strong>on</strong>.Simply put, the interpretati<strong>on</strong> of labour legislati<strong>on</strong>by the vested authorities may in fact yield ameasure of regulati<strong>on</strong> that is at odds with thoseproduced by surveys such as the DBS and ICAs.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reality, however, is that attempting to extendthe DBS measure into the realm of court judgementsand their orientati<strong>on</strong> is almost impossible.However, it is essential to note them in any discussi<strong>on</strong>that measures labour regulati<strong>on</strong> within acountry. Implicitly, legislative provisi<strong>on</strong>s representan incomplete and less than satisfying measureof labour regulati<strong>on</strong> in an ec<strong>on</strong>omy.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is another layer to understanding the legislativeenvir<strong>on</strong>ment in relati<strong>on</strong> to the labour market:In many countries, its labour law architectureflows from, and is intricately and deliberatelylinked to, both its internati<strong>on</strong>al and complementarydomestic legal obligati<strong>on</strong>s. Hence, drasticpolicy interventi<strong>on</strong>s designed to deregulate anec<strong>on</strong>omy’s labour market, may require due recogniti<strong>on</strong>of the ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s that a country hasalready ratified. In additi<strong>on</strong>, rights of an individualenshrined in the country’s c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> serveas the bedrock from which specific labour lawprovisi<strong>on</strong>s are made. Tampering with the latter ina substantive manner may indeed be unc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> generic point, however, is that shouldderegulating a labour market involve significant,163


legislative changes, it will critically impact <strong>on</strong> thebroader legal envir<strong>on</strong>ment of most countries. Insum, the noti<strong>on</strong> of deregulating a labour marketmay indeed have significant and possibly intractablelegal outcomes.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Envir<strong>on</strong>ment<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> extent to which the instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>mentrein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces or hinders legislativeprovisi<strong>on</strong>s is often under-appreciated in debatesaround labour market regulati<strong>on</strong>. In most ec<strong>on</strong>omies,instituti<strong>on</strong>s govern and manage the labourmarket. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se include employer and employeeorganisati<strong>on</strong>s; the courts of law including specialistcourts; instituti<strong>on</strong>s of dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>;ministries of labour or employment; collectivebargaining instituti<strong>on</strong>s; tripartite instituti<strong>on</strong>s andso <strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se instituti<strong>on</strong>s will be differentiallyresourced in human and physical terms; will yieldc<strong>on</strong>trasting per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mances according to pre-setobjectives; will have different governance structures,parameters of influence and ultimatelypower within the society and so <strong>on</strong>. Simply put,these range of factors, all of which are time andc<strong>on</strong>text-dependent, can and will fundamentallyalter the manner in which labour regulatory provisi<strong>on</strong>simpact <strong>on</strong> the ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Two examples would suffice: Firstly, a sectoralminimum wage regulati<strong>on</strong> mandated by governmentwill have little impact <strong>on</strong> either wages oremployment, if en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement and oversight of thisregulati<strong>on</strong> through the relevant instituti<strong>on</strong>s is ofa poor quality. In such a case, ec<strong>on</strong>omic outcomescould potentially be relatively benign if theinstituti<strong>on</strong>al oversight is weak and poor in quality.Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, in many developing countries, the courtsystem is poorly resourced and inefficient. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>rule of law takes a l<strong>on</strong>g time to be implementedin ec<strong>on</strong>omies with an inefficient judicial system.For labour law cases, this could mean that rigidityin the labour market is more about an inefficientjudiciary than any aspect of wages, uni<strong>on</strong> poweror indeed the labour legislati<strong>on</strong> itself. Ultimatelyhowever, the almost obvious point is that instituti<strong>on</strong>smatter, and nowhere more so than withinthe labour regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment.Instituti<strong>on</strong>s should also matter to ec<strong>on</strong>omistswhen examining the issue of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>.Apart from the binary variable issue noted above,or the idea that perfectly competitive output andfactor markets are the optimal outcomes, theimportance of instituti<strong>on</strong>s is often overlooked inthese debates. In our view, instituti<strong>on</strong>s that areefficient and complement the interacti<strong>on</strong> betweenindividuals are good <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> growth, and this fitswithin the classic understanding of an efficientlyfuncti<strong>on</strong>ing labour market. Especially high qualityinstituti<strong>on</strong>s can help to ensure that this marketfuncti<strong>on</strong>s efficiently and competitively. It is notclear that malfuncti<strong>on</strong>ing or n<strong>on</strong>-existent, instituti<strong>on</strong>sare an appropriate and acceptable c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an optimally functi<strong>on</strong>ing labour market.Heterogeneity in the Regulatory ArchitecturePerhaps <strong>on</strong>e of the key elements of this debatearound labour regulati<strong>on</strong>, growth and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malityis to acknowledge the distincti<strong>on</strong> between grades,types and levels of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>. This is an allusi<strong>on</strong>to the key, albeit obvious, point that there isa distincti<strong>on</strong> between the establishment and protecti<strong>on</strong>of core labour standards <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>e hand,and the more detailed specificati<strong>on</strong>s around thenature of hiring and firing clauses <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example. Itis often around the latter that much useful debateis to be had. However, it is important that the protecti<strong>on</strong>and promoti<strong>on</strong> of labour standards remainsat the core of any in-country labour market policyprogramme. This is critical to ensuring that thelabour rights agenda is complementary to a widerset of acti<strong>on</strong>s to improve both the quality of work164


and the quantity of employment opportunities inthe developing world. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> securing of core labourstandards we believe is at the core of promotingthe <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor and indeedthe kernel of a decent work agenda.Some recogniti<strong>on</strong>, however, needs to be given tothe possibility that labour regulati<strong>on</strong> bey<strong>on</strong>d corelabour standards may, under certain c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s,exacerbate segmentati<strong>on</strong> in the labour market.Aspects of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> may rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce theinsider-outsider divide by promoting barriers tohiring and firing. While this can reduce turnover,it may also affect employment growth.• Thirdly, we are of the opini<strong>on</strong> that more attenti<strong>on</strong>should be given to critical factors such asthe nature and quality of legal instituti<strong>on</strong>s andthe interpretati<strong>on</strong> of the law. Better governanceis str<strong>on</strong>gly correlated with ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth and prosperity.C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>sThis review of the ec<strong>on</strong>omic impact of labourregulati<strong>on</strong> has led us to draw the following policyc<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s:• First, a methodological c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>: we suggestcauti<strong>on</strong> in interpretati<strong>on</strong> of the published results,particularly from cross-country studies,and more importantly, their translati<strong>on</strong> intocountry-level policy interventi<strong>on</strong>s without duec<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> both to the heterogeneity in theregulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment, and country-specificc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. This is c<strong>on</strong>firmed both by the findingsin the Investment Climate Assessment,presented in the beginning of this secti<strong>on</strong>, andof the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s in the cross country analysismade by Loayza et al.• Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, we suggest a shift of focus from theideological questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> regulati<strong>on</strong> or deregulati<strong>on</strong>,to the questi<strong>on</strong> how such regulati<strong>on</strong> canbe used to promote decent work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the workingpoor. Thus, the debate <strong>on</strong> labour regulati<strong>on</strong>sshould focus <strong>on</strong> what is the right balancebetween security, supportive structures, andflexibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> firms in both the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal andin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.165


6. Principles and practicesof Labour Rights and <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> task of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor is to identify how legal instrumentscan be used to empower the poor. In thischapter we addresses <strong>on</strong>e of the key areas oflegal empowerment, namely how internati<strong>on</strong>aland nati<strong>on</strong>al systems of labour standards andlabour rights can become more inclusive andpromote more productive and decent work in thefight against poverty. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is - in this arena as inother arenas of legal empowerment - no quick fix<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> shifting from in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and low productive employmentto decent and productive employment.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no single soluti<strong>on</strong>, which can be appliedin all countries. A strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment hasto have comm<strong>on</strong> core principles but remain flexibleenough in design to fit many different ec<strong>on</strong>omic,social and political c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. It has tobe participatory, inclusive and gender sensitive.Some principles are basic <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> any re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategyin this field and they are introduced in Secti<strong>on</strong>6.1. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are many less<strong>on</strong>s to learn from recentnati<strong>on</strong>al and local initiatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment,which will be presented in Secti<strong>on</strong> 6.2. Somec<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s are drawn in 6.3. On the basis ofthese principles and practices, policy recommendati<strong>on</strong>sare introduced in Secti<strong>on</strong> 7.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> basic principles <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> inclusivere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mBoth promoti<strong>on</strong> of change - and management ofchange<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most successful countries, in terms of productiveemployment, are using a mix of ec<strong>on</strong>omicand social policies, implemented with flexibilityand designed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> security. Within the c<strong>on</strong>text ofcompetiti<strong>on</strong>, specialisati<strong>on</strong> and free trade, thisapproach helps to promote change and productivity;it also helps in the management of changeand in the creati<strong>on</strong> of decent work opportunities,a sense of inclusi<strong>on</strong> and a widely shared prosperity.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mix has varied from country to country,and the different policies are adjusted occasi<strong>on</strong>allyto improve the synergy between ec<strong>on</strong>omicand social policies, decent work and inclusi<strong>on</strong>.Both property rights - and labour rights<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> report from World <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> the SocialDimensi<strong>on</strong> of Globalisati<strong>on</strong> argued that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malactivities should be trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med and integratedinto a growing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector that provides decentjobs, incomes and protecti<strong>on</strong>. A balanced approachto upgrading the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy wouldrequire the systematic extensi<strong>on</strong> of propertyrights, accompanied by similar acti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> corelabour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all pers<strong>on</strong>s engaged in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malactivities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> report argues that such a trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>is an essential part of a nati<strong>on</strong>al strategyto reduce poverty and promote inclusi<strong>on</strong>. Whileit suggests that the key to empowering the poorthrough property rights is the provisi<strong>on</strong> of legalidentity to their assets, it also advances theunderstanding that the key to their empowermentthrough labour rights lies in c<strong>on</strong>ferring up<strong>on</strong>them a legal identity as workers or entrepreneurs,thereby making disguised commercial or employmentrelati<strong>on</strong>ships visible.Both protecti<strong>on</strong> - and fl exibility<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Development Report 2006, entitledEquity and Development, recognises the intrinsicvalue of equity and makes the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> investingin people, expanding access to justice, land, andinfrastructure, and promoting fairness in markets.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> report asks whether labour market instituti<strong>on</strong>scan be designed to be pro-growth and pro-166


equity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> key to success is to link employmentcreati<strong>on</strong> with protecti<strong>on</strong>. This requires buildingbroad societal c<strong>on</strong>sensus <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> coordinated re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msacross a variety of labour market instituti<strong>on</strong>s andprovisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> support to workers in re-entering thelabour market following investments in educati<strong>on</strong>and training, in incentives that would encouragemobility, and in job creati<strong>on</strong>, am<strong>on</strong>g othermeasures.Less<strong>on</strong>s from nati<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m practice<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are less<strong>on</strong>s to be learned from countrieswhich recently have introduced policies aimedat empowering workers and entrepreneurs in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.<strong>Legal</strong> identity<strong>Legal</strong> identity, as worker or entrepreneur, isof fundamental importance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment.Some countries have tried to establishthese identities and make the employmentrelati<strong>on</strong>ships explicit (in labour laws or in theirextensi<strong>on</strong>s). Thailand provides an example of howthe labour law has been extended to home workersthrough a ministerial regulati<strong>on</strong>. In this case,home workers are c<strong>on</strong>sidered ‘employees’ thosewho use raw materials and tools that come fromthe employer. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ministerial Regulati<strong>on</strong> also affirmsthe applicati<strong>on</strong> of the Fundamental principlesand rights at work to these workers (SeeCase 1, Annex 2). Employment relati<strong>on</strong>ships havealso been determined through judicial decisi<strong>on</strong>s.In the Philippines, the Supreme Court has applieda four-fold test in determining the existenceof an employer-employee relati<strong>on</strong>ship: 76 ‘(1) theselecti<strong>on</strong> and engagement of the employee; (2)the payment of wages; (3) the power of dismissal;and (4) the power to c<strong>on</strong>trol the employee’sc<strong>on</strong>duct.’ Furthermore, the evidence of payment— through a pay slip — has been accepted asproof of employer-employee relati<strong>on</strong>ship (SeeCase 2, Annex 2). India offers an example of awelfare fund where the trade uni<strong>on</strong>s provide acertificati<strong>on</strong> of the eligibility of the worker. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>identity there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e comes from membership in atrade uni<strong>on</strong> (See Case 3).Voice and representati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> right to voice and representati<strong>on</strong> is as importantas legal identity. Throughout the world, tradeuni<strong>on</strong>s are launching and supporting campaigns<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the representati<strong>on</strong> and protecti<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malworkers. For example, the Inter-American Regi<strong>on</strong>alOrganisati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers has issued guidelinesand manuals to enhance organisati<strong>on</strong> and representati<strong>on</strong>of workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Alliance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Zambia In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Associati<strong>on</strong>swas launched in 2002 in partnership withthe Zambia C<strong>on</strong>gress of Trade Uni<strong>on</strong>s. 77<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Self-Employed Women’s Associati<strong>on</strong> (SEWA),India, is the well-known and very promising tradeuni<strong>on</strong> of women in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers who actively engagein collective bargaining and otherwise leverageinfluence over the envir<strong>on</strong>ment in which theywork (See Case 4). Over the past two decades,SEWA has co-founded and inspired a number o<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ganisati<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers which individuallyand collectively are gaining voice and representati<strong>on</strong>in relevant policymaking <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>a.In Ghana, the ILO’s Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> programme hasworked with local government to promote socialdialogue by creating District Assembly Sub-Committees<strong>on</strong> Productive and Gainful Employmentthat include representatives of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises,in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers, the private sector, andgovernment. In the Philippines, local developmentcouncils are mandated <strong>on</strong> the regi<strong>on</strong>al,provincial, municipal and village-level wheredifferent interest groups, including registered andaccredited local organisati<strong>on</strong>s, are represented.167


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Homeless People’s Federati<strong>on</strong> Philippines,HPFP, participates in various municipal and village-leveldevelopment councils, including a fewlocal housing councils (See Case 5).Social protecti<strong>on</strong> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mRe<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of the social protecti<strong>on</strong> system is astrategic way to empower people. In India in2002, the Nati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Labour proposeda nati<strong>on</strong>al bill <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> workers in the unorganised(in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal) sector with the objective of regulating‘the employment and c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of serviceof unorganised sector workers and to provide <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>their safety, social security, health and welfare’.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> bill provides <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the establishment of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’Facilitati<strong>on</strong> Centres to support and assistunorganised workers, provides <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the setting upin the states of an Unorganised Sector <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’Welfare Fund, with funds from government andc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s by employers and registered workers;and sets out minimum c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of service,including hours of work and minimum wages (SeeCase 6). In India in 2007, the Nati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>on</strong> Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector(NCEUS) has drafted and proposed two nati<strong>on</strong>albills <strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of work and social securityof workers in the unorganised (in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal) sector:<strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> agricultural workers, the other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>-agriculturalworkers. Both bills incorporate provisi<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> regulating the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of work andsocial security of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> statutoryNati<strong>on</strong>al Social Security Scheme proposed by theNCEUS c<strong>on</strong>sists of the following package of minimumbenefits: illness, hospitalisati<strong>on</strong>, maternity,disability and life insurance, and old age pensi<strong>on</strong>.Other promising examples of extending socialprotecti<strong>on</strong> to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers are from Ghanaand the Philippines. In Ghana, with joint supportfrom the government and ILO’s Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> programme,associati<strong>on</strong>s and individuals who havejoined local credit uni<strong>on</strong>s are encouraged to enrolin the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Health Insurance Programme.In the Philippines, the statutory social securitysystem (SSS) and the health insurance schemeshave been progressively made universal throughvoluntary schemes that are open to self-employedworkers through lower-priced packages and awider network of collecti<strong>on</strong> units, including banksand organised groups (See Case 7). Notableexamples are also found in Latin America; theyinclude ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts in Mexico to extend social securitycoverage to the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector; innovati<strong>on</strong>s in socialcoverage of the Solidario programme in Chile;first rights-based health coverage in Chile, andc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al cash transfers in some 14 countriesbeginning with Brazil and Mexico.Improvement of the quality of labour marketinstituti<strong>on</strong>sSeveral countries have introduced re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to improvethe quality of labour market instituti<strong>on</strong>s. In2006, Chile introduced a re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in subc<strong>on</strong>tractingprocedures to include more workers in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallabour rights arrangements. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> objective is topromote subc<strong>on</strong>tracting, while at the same timeensuring compliance with all the labour obligati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> law introduced a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal arrangementbetween subc<strong>on</strong>tractors and the main firms tomeet a set of labour obligati<strong>on</strong>s. Direct resp<strong>on</strong>sibilitylies with the subc<strong>on</strong>tractor, but the mainfirm has the right to demand from the subc<strong>on</strong>tractora certificate of compliance issued by thelabour inspectorate agency and has the right towithhold payments from subc<strong>on</strong>tractors in casesin which there are pending obligati<strong>on</strong>s vis-à-vistheir workers (See Case 8).Spain has over the last 20-25 years introduced aseries of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of its <strong>on</strong>ce highly-regulated systemin an attempt to better balance the demandsof an open market ec<strong>on</strong>omy with the needs of168


works, first by allowing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an increase in theuse of fixed-term c<strong>on</strong>tracts, then by reintroducingc<strong>on</strong>straints in the use of temporary c<strong>on</strong>tractswhile easing employment protecti<strong>on</strong> legislati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> permanent workers. More recently Spanishtrade uni<strong>on</strong>s, employer organisati<strong>on</strong>s and governmentsigned an agreement to bring the use offixed-term work c<strong>on</strong>tracts more in line with theEuropean social model (See Case 9).<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment through alternative disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong>For poor people around the world, getting accessto courts and legal support to protecttheir rights is often impossible. In many cases,the reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this is straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward — they cannotaf<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d to pay the legal fees. In Tajikistan, theUK has helped to solve this problem by supportingThird Party Arbitrati<strong>on</strong> Courts. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se courtsare an alternative way of resolving disputes: twosides to a dispute agree to nominate a third partywho they both trust to mediate their disagreementand come to a decisi<strong>on</strong>. Although they operateindependently of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system, decisi<strong>on</strong>sare recognised by Tajikistan’s official courts.Third Party Arbitrati<strong>on</strong> Courts provide poor peoplewith a cheap, fair and accessible way of resolvingdisputes and protecting their rights. Third PartyArbitrati<strong>on</strong> has helped to make legal servicesavailable to 800,000 people in Tajikistan. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>approach has also been used successfully in Russia,Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Ukraine and Georgia(See Case 10).Improved business envir<strong>on</strong>ment<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank Investment Climate Survey illustratesthe need to improve the business envir<strong>on</strong>mentto encourage investment, entrepreneurshipand workers rights. Many countries have foundnew ways to support SMEs through various initiativeswith the aim of upgrading them into the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy (See Chapter 4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> examples).Simplifi cati<strong>on</strong> of c<strong>on</strong>tracting procedures<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Senegalese Government provides an exampleof a pro-active policy of c<strong>on</strong>tracting out publicinfrastructure projects to small scale c<strong>on</strong>tractors.In this case, bidding procedures and documentshave been substantially simplified in order topermit smaller c<strong>on</strong>tractors to participate in thebidding process. Bureaucratic documentati<strong>on</strong> isalso minimised and bidding documents c<strong>on</strong>tainofficial unit cost estimate in order to guide theless sophisticated c<strong>on</strong>tractor. A general sessi<strong>on</strong> isheld wherein c<strong>on</strong>tractors are told about the existenceof the implementing agency and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>medabout procedures, from the bidding to the awardingand implementati<strong>on</strong>. Simplificati<strong>on</strong> of theprocess goes as far as making the name of thewinner very clear in the announcement so thateven an illiterate c<strong>on</strong>tractor’s representative canreadily determine who was awarded the c<strong>on</strong>tract(See Case 11).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are also less<strong>on</strong>s to be learned from countriesthat have recently introduced policies aimedat empowering workers and entrepreneurs in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy through business rights (SeeChapter 4).169


C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legal empowerment<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> examples noted above illustrate how differentpolicies can be used to provide working peoplewith: Identity (India, the Philippines, Thailand);Voice and representati<strong>on</strong> (India); Social protecti<strong>on</strong>(Brazil, Chile, Ghana, India, Mexico, thePhilippines), and New ways to resolve disputes(Tajikistan).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se examples also dem<strong>on</strong>strate how differentpolicies can be used to improve the functi<strong>on</strong>ingof labour market instituti<strong>on</strong>s (Chile andThailand), and how they can work to adjust thebalance between protecti<strong>on</strong> and flexibility inresp<strong>on</strong>se to changing realities (Spain).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se and many other illustrati<strong>on</strong>s show thatre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is under way. Other countries can use theexamples and principles presented can be usedby other countries in their ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t to design strategies<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reis a need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> global acti<strong>on</strong> to c<strong>on</strong>vert these ‘goodnews’ approaches into a global movement.7. Towards a new socialc<strong>on</strong>tract: Policiesand Processes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong>EmpowermentPolicy recommendati<strong>on</strong>sBuilding <strong>on</strong> an emerging global social c<strong>on</strong>tract— the broad support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Fundamental Principlesand Rights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>agenda — we recommend that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>endorse the following priorities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentof those living and working in poverty:• Strengthen identity, voice, representati<strong>on</strong> anddialogue. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> process of legal empowermentstarts with identity. Just as property and physicalassets of the poor are recognised, so alsomust the greatest asset of the poor, namelytheir labour and human capital, be effectivelyrecognised. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a particular need toensure that workers and entrepreneurs in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy have the right to freedom ofassociati<strong>on</strong> through organisati<strong>on</strong>s of their ownchoosing and to collective bargaining, particularlywomen and youth who are over-representedin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Emphasis shouldbe placed <strong>on</strong> building up representativeorganisati<strong>on</strong>s of the working poor, particularlywage workers and self-employed operating inthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, to have voice, representati<strong>on</strong>and dialogue with <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyoperators and with public authorities in orderto defend their rights.• Strengthen the quality of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>and the effective en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of fundamentalprinciples and rights at work. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> purpose isto create synergies between protecti<strong>on</strong> andproductivity of the working poor and of theirassets. Reviewing the quality of instituti<strong>on</strong>s170


and of regulati<strong>on</strong>s should involve a critical andself-critical review of legal instruments fromthe point of view of their impacts <strong>on</strong> productivityand <strong>on</strong> the protecti<strong>on</strong> of labour.• Support applicati<strong>on</strong> of a minimum packageof labour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>aim should be that every country strives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> aminimum floor <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment that is realisticand en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable, as a basis to graduallystrengthen and extend applicati<strong>on</strong> of standards,taking into account productivity levelsand other nati<strong>on</strong>al circumstances. To this aima package of labour rights is proposed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy that upholds the Declarati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> Fundamental Principles and Rightsat <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> and three crucial aspects related toworking c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s: (1) health and safety atwork; (2) hours of work, and (3) minimumincome. It must be recognised that labourstandards at this minimum level c<strong>on</strong>stitutea basic floor <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment bey<strong>on</strong>d whichprogressive, rather than full, compliance isexpected. That is, we propose to build upprogressively from this basic floor throughinstituti<strong>on</strong>al approaches that are feasible even<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> producti<strong>on</strong> units with limited capacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>compliance. Strategies can aim at progressivecompliance and gradual c<strong>on</strong>vergence into aunified set of working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, as a goal.Some of the standards such as occupati<strong>on</strong>alsafety and health can be improved immediatelyat a low cost. Others can be achievedgradually through a developmental process ofawareness raising and capacity building.• Strengthen access to opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decentwork and to opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>,training and retraining, as well as combatingdiscriminati<strong>on</strong> to ensure efficient labourmarkets. This priority aims to promote changeand dynamism, linking private initiative withpublic policy so as to expand employment in agrowing and inclusive ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Labour rights,to be effective, should not exclude the workingpoor, nor c<strong>on</strong>strain their creative and entrepreneurialpotential. Opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>and capacity building as well as measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>combating discriminati<strong>on</strong> help increase legalrecogniti<strong>on</strong> of the poor and bring them closerto such ec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reorganisati<strong>on</strong>of producti<strong>on</strong> and distributi<strong>on</strong> throughsub-c<strong>on</strong>tracting and outsourcing is associatedwith the expansi<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment inthe supply chains. Private and public procurementrepresents, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, a practical yetstrategic policy lever through which to upgradethe productivity, incomes and working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sof the working poor. Integrating employmentcreati<strong>on</strong>, labour rights and decent workinto public and private procurement practicesis there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e a key mechanism to legally empowerthe poor. Often soluti<strong>on</strong>s to poverty andin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality can be found outside as well aswithin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Policies to createand provide improved access of the poorto new opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> full, productive andfreely chosen employment, as promoted in ILOC<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> 122, can provide a key mechanism<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowering the poor in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy and facilitating their transiti<strong>on</strong> to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality.• Support inclusive social protecti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>recogniti<strong>on</strong> of the rights to social security hasbeen developed through universally acceptedinstruments, such as the Universal Declarati<strong>on</strong>of Human Rights and the Internati<strong>on</strong>alCovenant <strong>on</strong> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Social and CulturalRights, which proclaim that social security isa fundamental societal right to which everyhuman is entitled. This promise must beupheld by all countries through laws, institu-171


ti<strong>on</strong>s and resp<strong>on</strong>sive mechanisms that couldprotect the poor from shocks and c<strong>on</strong>tingenciesthat can impoverish, and measures thatguarantee access to medical care, healthinsurance, old age pensi<strong>on</strong>s, and socialservices. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se mechanisms must not besolely dependent <strong>on</strong> the evidence of employmentstatus but must be open to all types ofworkers. From a systemic perspective, rightsto pensi<strong>on</strong>s and health protecti<strong>on</strong> should begranted to the people as citizens rather thanas workers, and they should be awarded <strong>on</strong>universality principles.We also recommend the following specific acti<strong>on</strong>sfavouring legal empowerment:• Ensure that legal empowerment becomes adriver <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> gender equality. Poverty has a genderdimensi<strong>on</strong>, and legal empowerment can helpdrive gender equality. A key challenge is toensure that ILO labour standards which promoteequality of opportunity and treatment areeffectively extended to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector workers.78 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> starting point <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this process may befound in the core labour standards <strong>on</strong> genderequality, namely, the Equal Remunerati<strong>on</strong>C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>, no.100, 1951; the C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>Discriminati<strong>on</strong> (Employment and Occupati<strong>on</strong>),no. 111, 1958. Much useful guidance can befound in the 1996 ILO Home <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>79 which mandates the extensi<strong>on</strong> of legalprotecti<strong>on</strong> and legal empowerment to homeworkers, who are predominantly women. Genderis already a mainstream priority in the integrati<strong>on</strong>of Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the PRSP work. Specificcapacity-building ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts have in particularbeen made in Bolivia, Brazil, Ecuador, Ethiopia,H<strong>on</strong>duras, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay andYemen to influence Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong> Strategies(PRSs) at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong> stage. A morein-depth process has been recently launchedto further c<strong>on</strong>solidate gender and employmentin three country PRS processes, namely inBurkina Faso, Liberia and the United Republicof Tanzania. This integrated approach includesenhancing the capacity of c<strong>on</strong>stituents <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mainstreaming gender equality in employment;facilitating gender budgeting of projected employmentprogrammes in the PRS acti<strong>on</strong> plans;building partnerships with other organisati<strong>on</strong>sat nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>al levels, which areinvolved in promoting gender equality in PRS.• Support legal empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenouspeople. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO Indigenous and Tribal PeoplesC<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> provides guidance and strategies<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment with respect not <strong>on</strong>lyto labour rights and protecti<strong>on</strong> of employment,but also with respect to land and propertyrights. Special ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their legal empowermentare dem<strong>on</strong>strated in an ‘ethnic audit’undertaken of 14 PRSPs as well as casestudies of country processes in Bolivia, Cambodia,Camero<strong>on</strong>, Guatemala and Nepal. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>research clearly showed that, although indigenouspeoples are disproporti<strong>on</strong>ately representedam<strong>on</strong>g the poor, their needs and prioritiesare generally not reflected in the strategiesemployed to combat poverty. Another c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>is research produced by the ILO anddebated at the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s PermanentForum <strong>on</strong> Indigenous Issues and within theInter-Agency Support Group. Subsequently,the World Bank organised an Internati<strong>on</strong>alC<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> Indigenous Peoples and PovertyReducti<strong>on</strong> (New York, May 2006) and committedto work towards the practical inclusi<strong>on</strong> ofindigenous peoples’ c<strong>on</strong>cerns in the PRSPs ina selected number of pilot countries in Africa,Asia and Latin America.172


Process recommendati<strong>on</strong>sOur working group recommends that the<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sider the following policyprocesses and instituti<strong>on</strong>al champi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theimplementati<strong>on</strong> of its recommendati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> legalempowerment through labour rights.• Promote nati<strong>on</strong>al development framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legal empowerment and decent work. Nati<strong>on</strong>algovernments and parliaments are resp<strong>on</strong>sible<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour rights and social c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s andbear a major resp<strong>on</strong>sibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m andeffectiveness of nati<strong>on</strong>al labour market instituti<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agenda proposes avalue-based framework that is best definedat the nati<strong>on</strong>al level through social dialogue.It does not propose a <strong>on</strong>e-size-fits-all soluti<strong>on</strong>,nor imply c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ality of any type. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>mix and sequencing of policy acti<strong>on</strong>s are tobe defined locally, taking account of diversityin the level of development, including financial,human, and instituti<strong>on</strong>al capacities, andimplemented through cooperati<strong>on</strong> betweengovernment, business, workers and society.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> intrinsic value of the Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Agendais to make employment a central goal of ec<strong>on</strong>omicpolicies and progressive improvementin the quality of work, including labour rightsand returns to labour as the main strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>moving people out of poverty. Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>Country Programmes (DWCPs) are the maintool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> driving this re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward inpartnership with all nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>alinstituti<strong>on</strong>s. DWCPs c<strong>on</strong>tribute to internati<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment frameworks such as povertyreducti<strong>on</strong> strategies, nati<strong>on</strong>al Millennium DevelopmentGoal strategies, the United Nati<strong>on</strong>sDevelopment Assistance Framework (UNDAF),and other integrated development plans.• Mobilise the Development Banks to supportnati<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m programmes. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategiesto include employment and labour rightswill need to be adapted to regi<strong>on</strong>al and localpriorities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e the Regi<strong>on</strong>al DevelopmentBanks, Political Organisati<strong>on</strong>s and UN organisati<strong>on</strong>scan be tapped as instituti<strong>on</strong>al champi<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m agenda <strong>on</strong> legal empowerment.Development Banks need to make legalempowerment a top priority, integrating accessto justice, property rights, labour rights andbusiness rights in <strong>on</strong>e comprehensive strategy<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> good governance of markets, to supportnati<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m processes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y need to seekthe support from regi<strong>on</strong>al political authoritiesand from the UN regi<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s.• Mobilise the principal actors of the global system,particularly the World Bank and the ILO,to work better together <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decent work. Two ofthe main global actors in the field of work anddevelopment, the ILO and the World Bank,have both c<strong>on</strong>tributed by developing instruments<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, the World Bank’s PRSs andthe ILO DWCPs. A key to a successful re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mprocess at the nati<strong>on</strong>al level is better policycoherence at the global level. <strong>Legal</strong> empowermentand re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of labour rights require closeco-operati<strong>on</strong> between governments, employersand workers, nati<strong>on</strong>ally and locally. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ywill need support in many <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms from theleading global instituti<strong>on</strong>s to build capacity.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> comm<strong>on</strong> goal should be to make labourmarkets work better — more efficient andmore equitable — <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> both workers and smallbusinesses.• Support voluntary initiatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentthrough labour rights. Codes of c<strong>on</strong>ductc<strong>on</strong>stitute a strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> motivating improvementsof the per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance of multinati<strong>on</strong>alcorporati<strong>on</strong>s. An increasing number of them,including that of the Ethical Trade Initiative,are based <strong>on</strong> ILO’s core labour standards, par-173


ticularly the prohibiti<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour, childlabour and discriminati<strong>on</strong> in the work place.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se codes of c<strong>on</strong>duct initiatives are alreadyplaying an important role, as businesses havebecome more sensitive and resp<strong>on</strong>sive to thec<strong>on</strong>cerns of ethical c<strong>on</strong>sumers.• Mobilise d<strong>on</strong>or countries to promote legal empowermentand decent work. D<strong>on</strong>or countriescould do a lot to support legal empowermentand the inclusi<strong>on</strong> of a decent work agenda inregi<strong>on</strong>al and nati<strong>on</strong>al strategies. For example,the EU is supporting the integrati<strong>on</strong> of decentwork goals in nati<strong>on</strong>al PRS processes in 60countries.• Promote a better understanding of the costsand benefits of legal empowerment throughdecent work. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> costs and benefits of undertakingre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming legal empowerment throughlabour rights and decent work need to beaddressed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first basic questi<strong>on</strong> is what arethe expected benefits of such re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m <strong>on</strong> productivityand thereby <strong>on</strong> prosperity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mainpurpose of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is to improve the qualityof labour market instituti<strong>on</strong>s and thereby thefuncti<strong>on</strong>ing of labour markets. Such re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms,provided they are well designed, should beseen as likely to enhance productivity. N<strong>on</strong>acti<strong>on</strong>,or maintaining the status quo, shouldbe seen as leaving a burden <strong>on</strong> the ec<strong>on</strong>omy.With income inequality growing ever largerwith worrying implicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sustainablesocieties, an ambitious re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m programmeintegrating <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorshould be seen as a necessity, not a luxury.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d basic questi<strong>on</strong> is the cost of startingand sustaining the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process and theaf<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dability of related policy initiatives. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reis no simple answer to that questi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>rewill be initial costs that have to be fundedmainly through restructuring of public expenditureprogrammes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> amount of costs andthe pay-back in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of higher quality oflabour market instituti<strong>on</strong>s will probably varybetween states, depending <strong>on</strong> policy designand the success of the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process. A successfulstrategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> integrating workers in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy — through, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example,integrating employment creati<strong>on</strong> programmeswith social protecti<strong>on</strong> systems - will broadenthe tax base and decrease unemployment,underemployment, decent work deficits, andother social costs, so that initial costs willso<strong>on</strong> be outweighed by benefits.• Strengthen the statistical base <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalempowerment. 80 Labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce and otherec<strong>on</strong>omic statistics need to be improved tofully capture the size and c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Although estimates of thesize and (less so) c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy are available in a growing number ofcountries, all <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment- especially women’s home-based producti<strong>on</strong>and disguised wage employment - are not yetfully visible in the official nati<strong>on</strong>al statisticsused to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal nati<strong>on</strong>al policies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalempowerment strategy must, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,include ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to make visible all <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment. This should include makingdisguised employment relati<strong>on</strong>ships moreexplicit; it should also make more visible boththe invisible supply chain and home-basedproducti<strong>on</strong>. Our working group recommendsthat improved labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce and ec<strong>on</strong>omic statisticsbe a priority goal <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al statisticalservices and be incorporated into the MillenniumDevelopment Indicators.174


Towards a New Social C<strong>on</strong>tract.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a tripartite c<strong>on</strong>sensus from employer,worker and government representatives <strong>on</strong> theneed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and effective legal systemwith guarantees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all citizens and enterprisesthat c<strong>on</strong>tracts are h<strong>on</strong>oured and upheld, therule of the law is respected and property rightsare secure. Such a legal system is a key c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>not <strong>on</strong>ly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> attracting investment, but also<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> generating certainty, and nurturing trust andfairness in society. 81 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> growing recogniti<strong>on</strong> ofthe need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour rights to catalyse employmentcreati<strong>on</strong> in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, while protectingits workers, has now led to an emerging globalsocial c<strong>on</strong>tract, a broad agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment. Labour rights, business rights,property rights and business rights taken togethercan <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the basis of this new social c<strong>on</strong>tract.Our <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chapter 3 suggests thatthe underpinnings of the new social c<strong>on</strong>tract <strong>on</strong>labour rights include five fundamental areas ofacti<strong>on</strong>, namely:- Strengthen identity, voice, representati<strong>on</strong> anddialogue.- Strengthen the quality of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>and the effective en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of fundamentalprinciples and rights at work.proposals are firmly based in the internati<strong>on</strong>al humanrights traditi<strong>on</strong>. Human rights are the basis<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Social c<strong>on</strong>tract. It is the obligati<strong>on</strong> of thestate as the primary duty bearer to protect andpromote these rights.• We use the word ‘c<strong>on</strong>tract’ to emphasise mutualresp<strong>on</strong>sibility. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> state has a duty to protectand the citizens have the right to protecti<strong>on</strong>— and obligati<strong>on</strong>s, which follow thereof.Employers and employees are also tied bymutual obligati<strong>on</strong>s. And large businesses havea duty not to exploit smaller businesses withwhich they have producti<strong>on</strong> or distributi<strong>on</strong>ties.• We use the word ‘global’ to emphasise the roleand resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of the actors at the internati<strong>on</strong>al,regi<strong>on</strong>al, nati<strong>on</strong>al and local levels.• We use the word ‘social’ to emphasise that theaim of this initiative is to improve the socialc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of people in poor countries, including:income, health, educati<strong>on</strong>, working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.• We have put ‘Towards’ be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e a Global SocialC<strong>on</strong>tract in the title of this report to emphasisdevelopment, process and time horiz<strong>on</strong>s.- Support applicati<strong>on</strong> of a minimum package oflabour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.- Strengthen access to opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decentwork and to opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>, trainingand retraining, as well as combating discriminati<strong>on</strong>to ensure efficient labour markets.- Support inclusive social protecti<strong>on</strong>.We recommend a new departure in internati<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment strategies, centred <strong>on</strong> the Decent<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> agenda as a Global Social C<strong>on</strong>tract. Our175


Annex 1:Recent and current initiatives toimprove statistics <strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omyWhat is clear from the statistics presented inthis Report is that the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy isfar larger than most people recognise. However,the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is still undercounted andundervalued in most countries. Few countries collectthe statistics needed to fully capture all <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment, both self-employmentand wage employment. Reflecting the assumpti<strong>on</strong>sunderlying labour regulati<strong>on</strong>s and labour ec<strong>on</strong>omics,- notably, the presumpti<strong>on</strong> of an explicit employer-employeerelati<strong>on</strong>ship — labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce andother ec<strong>on</strong>omic statistics do not always reflect thefull range of work arrangements and employmentstatuses.To generate more accurate and comprehensive statistics<strong>on</strong> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment and labour marketsmore generally, it is necessary to improve statisticalc<strong>on</strong>cepts and methods, including:• An expanded set of place of work indicators,including work at home, <strong>on</strong> the street, in fields,in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests, in waterways, or in the open air;• An expanded set of employment status indicators,including all types of self-employment,wage employment, and intermediary ambiguouscategories (such as independent c<strong>on</strong>tractorsand industrial outworkers);• Data <strong>on</strong> the socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic status of differentcategories of workers, including: level of earnings;legal status: c<strong>on</strong>tract versus no c<strong>on</strong>tract,registered versus n<strong>on</strong>-registered; working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s;and social protecti<strong>on</strong> coverage by typeand source (health insurance, old age pensi<strong>on</strong>s,disability insurance, unemployment insurance,life insurance, maternity, child care);Improved statistics would help to focus the attenti<strong>on</strong>of policymakers <strong>on</strong> the ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>sof the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and the linkagesbetween in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment and poverty. Morespecifically, improved labour-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce statistics thatcapture all <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment wouldserve to:• Increase the visibility of those who work in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, especially the least visibleand most vulnerable workers;• Advance understanding of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,including its c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth and its links with poverty;• In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the design of appropriate legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msand policies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the working poor in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy.Ideally, a unified framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> data collecti<strong>on</strong>would be developed — <strong>on</strong>e that allows <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theclassificati<strong>on</strong>, comparis<strong>on</strong>, and analysis of thefull set of employment statuses and work arrangementsthat exist in both developed and developingcountries.Fortunately, there are a number of recent and currentinitiatives to improve statistics <strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2002 Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ferenceand the 2003 Internati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>ference ofLabour Statisticians have endorsed an expandedstatistical definiti<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment thatincludes self-employment in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal (small unregistered)enterprises and wage employment inin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal (unprotected) jobs, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO Bureau ofStatistics, the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Expert Group <strong>on</strong> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malSector Statistics (Delhi Group), and the globalnetwork Women in In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Employment: Globalisingand Organising (WIEGO) are jointly producinga manual <strong>on</strong> surveys of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employmentso defined (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>thcoming in 2008). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Sub-Group176


<strong>on</strong> Gender Indicators of the Inter-Agency and ExpertGroup (IAEG) <strong>on</strong> MDG Indicators and the TaskForce <strong>on</strong> MDG #3 (Educati<strong>on</strong> and Gender Equality)have endorsed an indicator <strong>on</strong> the ‘structureof employment by type and sex’ developed by theILO Bureau of Statistics and WIEGO and a growingnumber of countries are using this indicatorto compile and present their nati<strong>on</strong>al labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cedata. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> System of Nati<strong>on</strong>al Accounts is currentlyrevising its chapter <strong>on</strong> measuring the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sectorc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to GDP.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> d<strong>on</strong>or community should support these initiativesto improve labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce and ec<strong>on</strong>omic statisticsand nati<strong>on</strong>al governments should use theexpanded statistical definiti<strong>on</strong> and related statisticalmethods in their collecti<strong>on</strong> of labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce andother ec<strong>on</strong>omic statistics.Annex 2:Country case experiencesCase 1:Extending Thailand’s labour lawthrough the Ministerial Regulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>home workers 82In Thailand, in 2004-05, the Ministry of Labourtook the initiative of drawing up ministerial regulati<strong>on</strong>sto extend the reach of the labour law tohome workers and agricultural workers. Homebasedworkers are defined as having the followingcharacteristics:1. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y receive c<strong>on</strong>tracts from an employer to produce,assemble, repair or process;2. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y work at a locati<strong>on</strong> that is not the establishmentof the employer;3. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y work to earn a wage;4. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y use all or part of raw materials or producti<strong>on</strong>instruments of the employer;5. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are c<strong>on</strong>tracted to work at home, and thework they do is a part or all of the producti<strong>on</strong>process or business of the employer.177Case 2:Judicial ruling <strong>on</strong> employmentrelati<strong>on</strong>ship in the Philippines<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Supreme Court in the Philippines, in landmarkdecisi<strong>on</strong>s, recognised an employer-employeerelati<strong>on</strong>ship in situati<strong>on</strong>s where this is ambiguous.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> said Supreme Court rulings upheld the statusof workers <strong>on</strong> commissi<strong>on</strong>, boundary, 83 piece-rateor task base and workers hired through a third partysuch as a recruitment agency.In determining the existence of an employer-employeerelati<strong>on</strong>ship, the Supreme Court 84 applied


the following four-fold test: ‘(1) the selecti<strong>on</strong> andengagement of the employee; (2) the payment ofwages; (3) the power of dismissal; and (4) thepower to c<strong>on</strong>trol the employee’s c<strong>on</strong>duct.’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Supreme Court insisted that, in the case oftransport operators, the owner of the public vehiclehas supervisi<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>trol over the driver.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> management of the business is in the owner’shands. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> owner as holder of the certificate ofpublic c<strong>on</strong>venience must see to it that the driverfollows the route prescribed by the franchising authorityand the rules promulgated as regards itsoperati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fact that the drivers do not receivefixed wages but get <strong>on</strong>ly that in excess of the socalled‘boundary’ they pay to the owner/operator isnot sufficient to withdraw the relati<strong>on</strong>ship betweenthem from that of employer and employee.Case 3:Welfare fund in India<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are workers who would not be able to participatein a c<strong>on</strong>tributory, voluntary scheme, no matterhow well designed such schemes are. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>erswho earn very little income or have seas<strong>on</strong>al workwould not likely be able to keep up with the requiredc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s.Recognising this c<strong>on</strong>straint, several states in Indiafound a soluti<strong>on</strong> in taxing the revenue that thesector generates, rather than the employers or theworkers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> funds raised from these levies, whichare Termed ‘welfare funds’, used <strong>on</strong> the welfare ofthe workers who produce the taxed products.India uses this system <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the benefit of those whoproduce bidis (hand-rolled cigarettes), mine workers,cine workers and workers in the building industry.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Bidi <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers Welfare Act (1976), <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance,provides the nati<strong>on</strong>al labour legislati<strong>on</strong> that taxesthe revenue generated by the sector (but not employers)to create a welfare fund administered bygovernment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are estimated to be over fourmilli<strong>on</strong> bide workers in India, 90 percent of whomare women. Most of them work under a sub-c<strong>on</strong>tractfrom their homes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a low piece rate and withoutaccess to health insurance or social security.Taxes of 50 paise (or half a rupee) per 1,000 bidisare levied. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> welfare fund operates hospitals anddispensaries, awards scholarships and providesschool supplies and uni<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Initially, the funddid not cover standard aspects of social protecti<strong>on</strong>such as sickness, occupati<strong>on</strong>al injury, maternity,disability, old age or survivors and unemploymentcoverage, but it has now been extended into groupinsurance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> which the welfare fund pays half.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Life Insurance Corporati<strong>on</strong> Insurance Schemesubsidises the other half. 85Welfare funds have also been set up also <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> workersin building and c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>. In Tamil Nadu,a tax of 0.1 to 0.3 percent is levied <strong>on</strong> the costof all building or c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> projects. This taxfinances the Tamil Nadu Scheme issued in 1994which prescribes the procedure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registeringmanual workers and the supply of identity cards.It also provides <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> crèches to look after the babiesof women c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> workers, a group accidentinsurance scheme, educati<strong>on</strong>al assistance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> s<strong>on</strong>sor daughters of registered workers, assistance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>marriage of the s<strong>on</strong> or daughter of the worker, assistanceto meet expenses towards the delivery ofa child, assistance to families of manual workerswho died due to accident or natural causes, andpensi<strong>on</strong> to cover every worker who has reached 60years and has been a member c<strong>on</strong>tinuously <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiveyears.A bill is also now pending that seeks to create asimilar welfare fund to cover the ‘unorganised sector’more broadly.178


Case 4:Collective identity, collectivebargaining and global impactIndustrial outworkers, whether in the garment,shoe, or electr<strong>on</strong>ic sectors, face a number of comm<strong>on</strong>problems, am<strong>on</strong>g them: low piece-rates andearnings; irregularity of work; irregular and (often)delayed payments and the costs of providing/maintainingworkspace, utilities, and equipment.In additi<strong>on</strong>, some endure harsh or dangerous workingc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s — <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, shoe makers are exposedto toxic glues and many other workers suffersore backs and deteriorating eye sight from workingin badly-equipped and poorly-lit workplaces(often their own homes).SEWA has a l<strong>on</strong>g history of working with garmentworkers focusing primarily <strong>on</strong> negotiating higherpiece-rates and fairer working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> garmentindustrial outworkers, many of whom are Muslim.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se organizing ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts have involved negotiati<strong>on</strong>swith the Labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>er — as well asrallies in fr<strong>on</strong>t of his office — to demand minimumwage, identity cards, and welfare schemes (childcare,health care, and school scholarships) <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> subc<strong>on</strong>tractedgarment workers.In 1986, SEWA was able to get a minimum wage <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>garment stitching (89.60 rupees per day) includedin the official Gujarat state Schedule of minimumwages under the Minimum Wages Act. 86 Over theyears, SEWA has also helped ‘own account’ garmentmakers to acquire new skills, improved equipment,and market in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> to try to compete inthe fast-changing local garment market. This hasincluded loans <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improved sewing machines andrelated gadgets, training at the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Institute ofFashi<strong>on</strong> Technology (NIFT), and installing electricityin the homes of SEWA members (to avoid thehigh costs of tapping electricity illegally).In recent years, as export-oriented, factory-basedgarment producti<strong>on</strong> has expanded in AhmadabadCity, SEWA has begun to organise waged workersin garment factories as well.During the 1980s, SEWA began establishing linkageswith membership-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s ofhome-based workers and street vendors and NGOsworking with these groups. In the mid-1990s, attwo separate meetings in Europe, these organisati<strong>on</strong>scame together under SEWA’s leadership to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m two internati<strong>on</strong>al alliances — <strong>on</strong>e of organisati<strong>on</strong>sof home-based workers, the other of organisati<strong>on</strong>sof street vendors.From its incepti<strong>on</strong>, the alliance of home-basedworker organisati<strong>on</strong>s was centrally involved in thecampaign to pass an Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Organizati<strong>on</strong>(ILO) c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> home work. To helpwith the campaign, SEWA and its allies promotedresearch ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to compile and analyse existingdata <strong>on</strong> home workers worldwide, and UNIFEM wasasked to c<strong>on</strong>vene an Asia regi<strong>on</strong> policy dialogue<strong>on</strong> home workers that included government representatives.With the passage of the ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> Home <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in 1996, SEWA and HomeNetrecognised the power of statistics and of ‘joint acti<strong>on</strong>’of activists, researchers, and policymakers.This recogniti<strong>on</strong> led to the 1997 global acti<strong>on</strong>-research-policynetwork called WIEGO which servesas a think-tank <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the growing global movement ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers.In 1995, SEWA organised a meeting of representativesof street vendor organisati<strong>on</strong>s from a dozenof cities around the world as well as activistsand lawyers working with them at the RockefellerFoundati<strong>on</strong> Study and C<strong>on</strong>ference Centre in Bellagio,Italy. At that meeting, the participants draftedthe Bellagio Internati<strong>on</strong>al Declarati<strong>on</strong> of StreetVendors which calls <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> acti<strong>on</strong> by individual traders,traders’ associati<strong>on</strong>s, city governments, andinternati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s including the United179


Nati<strong>on</strong>s, the ILO and the World Bank. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> participantsalso called <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the establishment of an internati<strong>on</strong>alnetwork of street vendor organisati<strong>on</strong>sto be called StreetNet. In early 2000, a StreetNetoffice was set up in Durban, South Africa. In November2002, after several regi<strong>on</strong>al meetings ofstreet vendor organisati<strong>on</strong>s, StreetNet Internati<strong>on</strong>alwas officially launched. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> aim of StreetNet isto promote the exchange of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and ideas<strong>on</strong> critical issues facing street vendors, marketvendors and hawkers (i.e. mobile vendors) and <strong>on</strong>practical organising and advocacy strategies.Membership-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s (uni<strong>on</strong>s, co-operativesor associati<strong>on</strong>s) directly organising streetvendors, market vendors and/or hawkers am<strong>on</strong>gtheir members, are entitled to become affiliated toStreetNet Internati<strong>on</strong>al. As of late 2007, Street-Net Internati<strong>on</strong>al had 34 affiliates in 30 countries,including: local associati<strong>on</strong>s or trade uni<strong>on</strong>s, nati<strong>on</strong>alfederati<strong>on</strong>s or associati<strong>on</strong>s, and regi<strong>on</strong>al alliances.Over the past decade, SEWA has also co-foundedor inspired nati<strong>on</strong>al and regi<strong>on</strong>al branches ofhome workers and their allies (called HomeNets)in South-East and South Asia, and nati<strong>on</strong>al alliancesof street vendors in India and Kenya. It alsoserves <strong>on</strong> an internati<strong>on</strong>al coordinating committeethat has organised three regi<strong>on</strong>al and two internati<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>ferences of organisati<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malworkers; and as advisor to an internati<strong>on</strong>al steeringcommittee that is planning the first internati<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>ference of organisati<strong>on</strong>s of waste collectors tobe held in Columbia in early 2008.Together, these organisati<strong>on</strong>s have helped foster aglobal movement of workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omythat now includes local trade uni<strong>on</strong>s and othermembership-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers,nati<strong>on</strong>al and global trade uni<strong>on</strong> federati<strong>on</strong>s thathave begun organising in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers, severalnati<strong>on</strong>al federati<strong>on</strong>s of workers’ educati<strong>on</strong> associati<strong>on</strong>s,the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Federati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’ Educati<strong>on</strong>Associati<strong>on</strong>s (IFWEA), eight nati<strong>on</strong>al andtwo regi<strong>on</strong>al HomeNets, StreetNet Internati<strong>on</strong>al,and the WIEGO network. Drawing inspirati<strong>on</strong> andguidance from SEWA, this movement c<strong>on</strong>tinues toidentify and network with organisati<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malworkers and to enlighten and influence policy debates<strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Case 5:Federati<strong>on</strong> of urban poor participatingin governance<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Homeless People’s Federati<strong>on</strong> Philippines(HPFP) is a self-help, community-based federati<strong>on</strong>that promotes savings mobilisati<strong>on</strong> in low-incomecommunities as a way of building their financialcapacity to invest in their own development. HPFPworks towards securing land tenure, upgradingsettlements and uplifting the ec<strong>on</strong>omic status ofits members. It uses savings mainly as a strategy,not <strong>on</strong>ly to finance community investments butalso to bring people together to work towards theircomm<strong>on</strong> goals. HPFP is thus not <strong>on</strong>ly a financialtool but also a social mechanism, which buildsnetworks of communities that foster c<strong>on</strong>tinuouslearning and innovati<strong>on</strong>, partnerships and supportsystems. This network of communities opens upnew possibilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> negotiati<strong>on</strong>s with the stateand, am<strong>on</strong>g other things, the realisati<strong>on</strong> of new<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of partnership.In relati<strong>on</strong> to its partnerships with public instituti<strong>on</strong>s,the federati<strong>on</strong> deems it important to berecognised as a partner of barangays — villagelevel governance units that are the first line of engagementwith communities — and to participatein <strong>on</strong>e important mechanism available to people’sorganisati<strong>on</strong>s and NGOs, namely the barangay developmentcouncil, where barangay physical, eco-180


nomic and social development plans and budgetsare prepared and approved. Barangay plans andprojects have a palpable impact <strong>on</strong> communities.Road projects, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, can lead to dislocati<strong>on</strong>of some communities, and health-related projectsmay overlap rather than complement communityinitiatedfacilities.In general, local development councils are mandatedat all levels, from the barangays up to thecities and provinces. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y were created to encouragepeople’s participati<strong>on</strong> in governance andthereby to promote transparency in all local governmenttransacti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> barangay developmentcouncil, in particular, is a vehicle that ensures theparticipati<strong>on</strong> of civil society groups in the choice ofdevelopment projects and in the appropriati<strong>on</strong> anduse of funds, so that these are not the sole resp<strong>on</strong>sibilityof barangay officials. HPFP leaders lobbiedsuccessfully <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the activati<strong>on</strong> of a barangay developmentcouncil in Quez<strong>on</strong> City, <strong>on</strong> which thereare as HPFP representatives, and HPFP leadersare also members of the city development councilof General Santos City. However, the experience ofthe federati<strong>on</strong> is that without local pressure, thesecouncils may not operate effectively and may exist<strong>on</strong>ly in name.Engaging government and private agencies did notcome easily to the HPFP. Communities still struggleas they interact with government and privateentities that are not accustomed to dealing withthe poor <strong>on</strong> an equal footing. Below are some strategiesthat the HPFP has learned to adopt throughyears of engagement with public and private agencies.Alignment with electoral cycles: One of the less<strong>on</strong>sfrom previous engagement experiences is that anyprojects or c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s approved by elected officialsshould be completed within the electoralperiod. Thus, planning must also be aligned withelectoral cycles.Establishing relati<strong>on</strong>ships with career officials:Despite changes in elected officials, the HPFPcan maintain relati<strong>on</strong>ships with career officials,who retain their positi<strong>on</strong>s even after changes inpolitical leadership. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> HPFP c<strong>on</strong>tinues to receivesupport from career officials, some of whomendorse the officials.Show of numbers and a broad network: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> HPFPalso uses its nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>al network toobtain c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s from public agencies, and therehave been instances where government officialsand landowners have agreed to certain c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>swhen these were requested in the presenceof large numbers of people. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> federati<strong>on</strong> hasused its internati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s and its membershipin internati<strong>on</strong>al groups (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, theShack/Slum Dwellers Internati<strong>on</strong>al) to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce closerrelati<strong>on</strong>ships with important public officials. It hasalso invited public officials to participate in multilateralprojects and internati<strong>on</strong>al exchanges, thushelping to c<strong>on</strong>solidate individual relati<strong>on</strong>ships andidentify win—win strategies.Capitalising <strong>on</strong> its track record and the HPFP nameto bolster local ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> HPFP has earned credibilitywith government and private organisati<strong>on</strong>sthrough its self-help ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts in mobilising savingsand securing land tenure. Government functi<strong>on</strong>ariesand private agencies usually ignore HPFPcommunities until they find out about the financialstake members have invested in their work, thegains they have achieved through their own initiativeand the networks that they have been able toestablish.Strengthening technical know-how. Needless to say,good technical know-how is critical to taking a principledand in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med positi<strong>on</strong> when negotiating. Unlesscommunity associati<strong>on</strong>s know how to expresstheir interests in operati<strong>on</strong>al terms, they will not be181


able to go bey<strong>on</strong>d general statements of intent, andmay inevitably fall prey to unscrupulous parties whocan c<strong>on</strong>ceal their intent behind complex terminology,legalese, mathematical <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulae and unverifieddocuments. Building technical skills is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ean important comp<strong>on</strong>ent of successful engagementwith the state. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> HPFP makes it a point to sharein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and transfer their knowledge to a widerange of communities. 87Case 6:Legislative Initiatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Unorganised<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ersTwo legal initiatives in India are described belowc<strong>on</strong>cerning Unorganised <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers. 88Unorganised Sector <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers (Employment andWelfare) Bill, IndiaAt present, the Government of India is actively reviewinga nati<strong>on</strong>al bill <strong>on</strong> workers in the unorganisedsector, which was drafted by the Nati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>on</strong> Labour and submitted to Parliament in2002. This Bill has the objectives of regulating ‘theemployment and c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of service of unorganisedsector workers and to provide <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their safety,social security, health and welfare.’ 89 It defines aworker as ‘a pers<strong>on</strong> engaged in Scheduled Employmentwhether <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> any remunerati<strong>on</strong> or otherwise.’(Some 122 occupati<strong>on</strong>s are listed as ScheduledEmployment.) <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> bill, furthermore, provides <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the establishment of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’ Facilitati<strong>on</strong> Centresto support and assist unorganised workers, who:1) are resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registrati<strong>on</strong> of workers and<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> guidance <strong>on</strong> a range of issues, such as disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong>, self-help groups and schemes available<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their benefit; 2) will maintain a register of workersand provide an identity card and social securitynumber and 3) will be resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulatingsafety and social security schemes, includinghealth and medical care, employment injury benefit,maternity benefit, old age pensi<strong>on</strong> and safetymeasures.Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, the bill provides <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the setting up,at state level, of an Unorganised Sector <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’Welfare Fund, supported with funds from government,employers and registered workers. It alsosets out minimum c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of service, includinghours of work and minimum wages.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is an attempt as well to safeguard the rightsof women. Wage discriminati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the grounds ofgender is prohibited and a female worker is entitledto ‘such maternity benefits with wages asprescribed.’ Employers are also liable to pay compensati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> injury <strong>on</strong> duty. (Source: Governmentof India, 2003)Unorganised Sector <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’ Social SecurityScheme, IndiaOver 90 percent of India’s workers are in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy (including agricultural workers),with little, if any, statutory social security. Most arecasual labourers, c<strong>on</strong>tract and piece-rate workersand self-employed own-account workers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Governmentof India recently launched the UnorganisedSector <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’ Social Security Scheme <strong>on</strong> apilot basis in 50 districts. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> scheme provides <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>three basic protecti<strong>on</strong>s: old age pensi<strong>on</strong>, pers<strong>on</strong>alaccident insurance, and medical insurance. It iscompulsory <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registered employees and voluntary<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-employed workers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers c<strong>on</strong>tribute tothe scheme, as do employers. Where self-employedworkers join the scheme, they pay worker and employerc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s. Government also c<strong>on</strong>tributes.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers Facilitati<strong>on</strong> Centres are being set up toassist workers (see above under Securing Rightsof In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> scheme will be administeredthrough the already existing Employee ProvidentFund Organisati<strong>on</strong> offices around the country(Source: Government of India, 2004).182


Case 7:Social security <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all in thePhilippinesIn the Philippines, two complementary facilities -the statutory social security system and the healthinsurance scheme — are being made progressivelyaccessible to every<strong>on</strong>e through voluntary schemesthat are open to self-employed workers, lowerpricedpackages and a wider network of collecti<strong>on</strong>units, including banks and organised groups.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Philippines Social Security System (SSS) offersa comprehensive range of cash benefits asinsurance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> retirement, death, disability, maternity,sickness, old age, death and work-relatedinjuries. In 1995, it extended membership to thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector under its self-employed and voluntarymembership scheme. Under this scheme,the minimum m<strong>on</strong>thly salary to qualify as an SSSmember was lowered to P1,000 and the definiti<strong>on</strong>of self-employed was expanded to ‘all selfemployedpers<strong>on</strong>s regardless of trade, business oroccupati<strong>on</strong>, with a m<strong>on</strong>thly net income of at leastP1,000.’ This definiti<strong>on</strong> would include householdhelp, individual farmers, fisher folk and othersmall entrepreneurs who may join the scheme asvoluntary members. 90As of December 2002, SSS covered about 24.3milli<strong>on</strong> members, of whom 4.5 milli<strong>on</strong> are self-employedor working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. However,the scheme c<strong>on</strong>tinues to have problems withcompliance, and workers often blame n<strong>on</strong>-membership<strong>on</strong> lack of time, lack of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, lackof regular employment, cost of c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s, anddifficulties trying to c<strong>on</strong>tact SSS representatives.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Philippine Health Insurance Corporati<strong>on</strong> (Phil-Health) used to be integrated with the Social SecuritySystem, but was separated, in part, to lowerthe cost of medical insurance package <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> householdsthat set their priorities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> immediate ratherthan the l<strong>on</strong>ger-term medical needs covered bythe SSS. Phil-Health administers health insuranceand provides hospitalisati<strong>on</strong> as well as out-patientbenefits to its members and their beneficiaries intimes of need and illness.Phil-Health has expanded its programme to includethose working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy through the‘Individually Paying Programme’ (IPP). In 2002,Phil-Health covered 54.6 milli<strong>on</strong> Filipinos, or 64percent of the country’s projected populati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>December 2005. Of the total covered, 54 percentare employed; 15 percent are individual payers;sp<strong>on</strong>sor 22 percent by third parties, and 0.6 aren<strong>on</strong>-paying members. Individual payers includethe self-employed (market vendors, farmers, fisherfolk),private practiti<strong>on</strong>ers and professi<strong>on</strong>als(doctors, lawyers), and those separated from work.With 2.9 milli<strong>on</strong> members as of March 2006, it iscalculated that IPP membership grows by an averageof 30 percent each year.Under the IPP, household heads pay a m<strong>on</strong>thlyc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>on</strong>ly P100 (currently just over $2)to have their families covered by health insurance.This entitles members and their dependentsto limited hospital coverage <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> room and board,laboratory tests, medicines and doctors’ fees whenc<strong>on</strong>fined in a hospital. Phil-Health has furtherpilot-tested a partnership with organised groupssuch as cooperatives to facilitate its reach to thosewho are difficult to reach individually.Lowering the cost of insurance packages, allowingmore frequent collecti<strong>on</strong>, and partnering withorganised groups, could serve to make such voluntaryschemes available to all.183


Case 8:Minimum Living Standard SecuritySystem in ChinaIn 1993, the Chinese government began to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mthe social relief system in cities, at the same timeseeking to try out a minimum living standard securitysystem. In 1999, this security system wasestablished in all cities and county towns throughoutthe country. In the same year, the Chinesegovernment officially promulgated the Regulati<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> Guaranteeing Urban Residents’ Minimum Standardof Living to ensure the basic livelihood of allurban residents. This has been decided ‘primarily<strong>on</strong> the basis of urban residents’ average incomeand c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> level per capita, the price levelof the previous year, the c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> price index,the local cost necessary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> maintaining the basiclivelihood, other c<strong>on</strong>nected social security standards,the materials <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the basic needs of food,clothing and housing, and the expenditure <strong>on</strong> under-agechildren’s compulsory educati<strong>on</strong>.’ 91Funds <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this purpose are included in the fiscalbudgets of the local people’s governments, whichdetermine the minimum living standard accordingto the cost necessary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> maintaining the basiclivelihood of the local urbanites. Urban residentswith an average family income lower than the minimumliving standard can apply <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the minimumliving allowance. Investigati<strong>on</strong> of the family’s incomeshall be c<strong>on</strong>ducted be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e issuance of theminimum living allowance, the level of which iscalculated in terms of the difference between thefamily per-capita income and the minimum livingstandard.Case 9:Labour protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> subc<strong>on</strong>tractsin ChileIn 2006, a law regulating subc<strong>on</strong>tracting was introducedin Chile. According to the Ministry ofLabour, 35 percent of workers in Chile are notdirectly hired by large firms finding work insteadthrough subc<strong>on</strong>tractors or other providers of pers<strong>on</strong>nel.At present, resp<strong>on</strong>sibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour obligati<strong>on</strong>srests with the hiring firm. Compliance isoften low and capacity to pay limited, particularlyin the case of pers<strong>on</strong>nel suppliers who can operatewith little capital. In this way, labour obligati<strong>on</strong>sare thoroughly diluted. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> situati<strong>on</strong> is such thatsome hiring firms are themselves creati<strong>on</strong>s of theprincipal firms.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> law introduced in Chile regulates both typesof arrangements, but the objective is to limit thesupply of labour to <strong>on</strong>ly short-term replacementworkers. In the case of subc<strong>on</strong>tracting, the objectiveis to promote it but to ensure compliance withall the labour obligati<strong>on</strong>s, as follows:• A deposit of a re-adjustable guarantee (nearlyUS$9000 at recent exchange rates) is required<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the providers of labour, and the deposit canbe used in cases of n<strong>on</strong>-compliance and a timelimit of six m<strong>on</strong>ths has been introduced <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thec<strong>on</strong>tracts.• In the case of subc<strong>on</strong>tracting, provisi<strong>on</strong>s wereintroduced <strong>on</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>sibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the labour obligati<strong>on</strong>s,which affect both subc<strong>on</strong>tractors andthe main firms regarding resp<strong>on</strong>sibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thelabour obligati<strong>on</strong>s. Direct resp<strong>on</strong>sibility lies withthe subc<strong>on</strong>tractors, but the main firms have theright to request from the subc<strong>on</strong>tractor a certificateof compliance (issued by the labour inspectorateagency), and they also have the right towithhold payments <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> subc<strong>on</strong>tractors in cases ofobligati<strong>on</strong>s still pending. In fact, the law trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msthe principal firm into an instrument of la-184


our inspecti<strong>on</strong> and sancti<strong>on</strong> and it ensures thatcompliance will increase. 92Case 10:Spain: Flexibility at the margin 93In Spain, a two-tiered hierarchy of standards wasapplied to different categories of workers — withflexibility allowed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> new entrants and unemployedpers<strong>on</strong>s (to encourage firms to hire them) and ac<strong>on</strong>tinued level of protecti<strong>on</strong> kept <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> permanentworkers (to avoid threatening the entire work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cewith job insecurity).High unemployment rates during the first half ofthe 1980s in Spain triggered the adopti<strong>on</strong> measuresto regulate c<strong>on</strong>tracts of limited durati<strong>on</strong> (orfixed term c<strong>on</strong>tracts) to ensure that they met minimumstandards of employment c<strong>on</strong>tracts whileleaving employment protecti<strong>on</strong> legislati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> permanentworkers untouched. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se c<strong>on</strong>tracts havelower dismissal costs and offer social securityrebates <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the first two years of the c<strong>on</strong>tract. Itis applicable <strong>on</strong>ly to workers below 30 years orover 45 years, l<strong>on</strong>g-term unemployed and disabledworkers.Overall, fixed-term c<strong>on</strong>tracts have been instrumentalin increasing employment in Spain while maintaininga certain degree of labour rights. This hasbenefited some specific groups of workers, mainlylow skilled, and is clearly a better opti<strong>on</strong> than remainingunemployed. 94In 2006, Spanish trade uni<strong>on</strong>s, employers’ organisati<strong>on</strong>sand government signed an agreement toprovide additi<strong>on</strong>al safeguards within these c<strong>on</strong>tracts,and to bring c<strong>on</strong>tractual arrangements moreinto line with the European social model. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mainpoints of the agreement are as follows:• After more than 24 m<strong>on</strong>ths <strong>on</strong> a fixed-termc<strong>on</strong>tract in the same enterprise and doing thesame job, over a reference period of 30 m<strong>on</strong>ths,the worker’s c<strong>on</strong>tract becomes <strong>on</strong>e of indefinitedurati<strong>on</strong>;• Employer b<strong>on</strong>uses <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> four years when targetgroups (women, youngsters, and l<strong>on</strong>ger-term unemployed)are offered an open-ended c<strong>on</strong>tract;• Precise definiti<strong>on</strong> of and acti<strong>on</strong> against illegalposting of workers between firms;• Cuts in employer social security c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>;• Extended unemployment benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> olderworkers, and measures to increase protecti<strong>on</strong>of flexible fixed-term workers.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> success of fixed-term c<strong>on</strong>tracts in Spain is stilla matter of discussi<strong>on</strong>. Given the strict regulati<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> permanent employment, the main attractivenessof fixed term c<strong>on</strong>tracts is the flexibility andlow firing costs they entail. This kind of c<strong>on</strong>tractsallows <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a quick adaptati<strong>on</strong> of the staff to changingec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.An important element in the assessment of fixedtermc<strong>on</strong>tracts is whether workers with temporaryarrangements are trapped in this situati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> al<strong>on</strong>g time or, <strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>trary, can obtain a permanentjob after a relatively short period. It is saidthat fixed-term c<strong>on</strong>tracts could serve as screeningdevices that allow employers to observe workers’per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance. Skilful workers would thus obtain apermanent c<strong>on</strong>tract after a probati<strong>on</strong> period holdinga fixed-term c<strong>on</strong>tract. 95 However, this transiti<strong>on</strong>from a temporary to a permanent post in Spain is,in general, rather slow and takes l<strong>on</strong>ger at presentthan in the past. 96<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> disadvantages of this measure must also benoted. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, little incentive as aresult either <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> employers or workers to invest inhuman capital and reduced overall labour mobility,due to inherent uncertainty, lower remunerati<strong>on</strong>and high housing costs.185


Case 11:China’s positive resp<strong>on</strong>ses to growingmarket ec<strong>on</strong>omySince the founding of the People’s Republicof China in 1949, a planned ec<strong>on</strong>omic systemhas been adopted, whereby highly c<strong>on</strong>centratedemployment and wage and labour systemsguaranteed the livelihood of employees, and alsopromoted social security.However, this system has had to adapt with thechanges in ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social development, particularlysince 1978, when China began its policyof re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and opening up. This period was markedby a focus <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> that swiftlymoved towards what has been called a ‘socialistmarket ec<strong>on</strong>omy system.’As a result, labour and social security structuresunderwent many changes. Most obviously, Chinaexperienced unprecedented ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth ofbetween eight to 12 percent, far exceeding thecentralised and collective growth patterns. This inturn affected employment patterns in cities withlarge urban migrati<strong>on</strong> from rural areas, un-c<strong>on</strong>tractedhires, l<strong>on</strong>g working hours, and low wages,with little or no job security or safety protecti<strong>on</strong>.Meanwhile, rural unemployment was also <strong>on</strong> theincrease and the gulf between classes was widening.It is estimated that there are more than 150milli<strong>on</strong> redundant rural labourers, with an unemploymentrate in urban areas and townships standingat over four percent.However, the most far reaching ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to changethe law were announced in March 2006 by PremierWen Jiabao in his annual speech at the Nati<strong>on</strong>alPeople’s C<strong>on</strong>gress. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> wide ranging ec<strong>on</strong>omic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mpackage includes a new labour law addressingworking c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in China. With some amendments,influenced to some extent by the ILO, thenew labour ruling has become law taking effect 1January 2008. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> State is now declared to haveobligati<strong>on</strong>s, good governance, better public instituti<strong>on</strong>s,protecti<strong>on</strong> clauses, c<strong>on</strong>tracts, regulati<strong>on</strong>sand legal arbitrati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m package indicatesthat the State will play a crucial role by rethinkingdevelopment strategies and having solidpolicies in place. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> following features are themost important of the new labour initiatives:• Most industrial employees, including migrantworkers are covered;• Provisi<strong>on</strong>s are clarified <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> collective c<strong>on</strong>tractsthat apply to groups of workers and employersindustry-wide or within a given regi<strong>on</strong>;• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> employer must account <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> any deviati<strong>on</strong>from the labour standards imposed by law,which also includes a requirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> them toprovide written c<strong>on</strong>tracts;• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> courts will take a more stringent approachto labour violati<strong>on</strong>s as per the new laws. In fact,should the employer be found in violati<strong>on</strong> ofeither the law or even ‘administrative regulati<strong>on</strong>s’,the labour administrati<strong>on</strong> has the powerto issue warnings or ‘rectificati<strong>on</strong>s’ depending<strong>on</strong> the severity of the violati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are alsoprovisi<strong>on</strong>s within the law <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> damages and evencriminal liability in those cases where labourrights are grossly infringed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> law strictlylimits tacking <strong>on</strong> probati<strong>on</strong>ary periods duringwhich the employer can arbitrarily terminate anemployee. This feature is designed to overcomean abusive practice that deprives employeesof protecti<strong>on</strong>s from arbitrary discharge and requires‘just cause’ be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e an employee is dismissed;• This proposed law regulates <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the first timethe new industry of labour brokers or ‘labourdispatchers,’ which has grown up to furnish exportindustries with ‘just-in-time’ workers whohave dubious legal status as employees under186


the law and there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e are often unprotected;• If employers keep using a temporary employee<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> more than two fixed — term c<strong>on</strong>tracts, thec<strong>on</strong>tract has to be c<strong>on</strong>verted into an indefiniteterm c<strong>on</strong>tract, thus ending the practice of ‘casualising’employment;• This draft law regulates abuses of ‘n<strong>on</strong>-compete’clauses, whereby employers saddle skilledworkers in IT and other sectors with excessiverestricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> who they can work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the futureand severely hamper future job mobilitywith legal entanglements.To correct a predispositi<strong>on</strong> in Chinese courts andam<strong>on</strong>g labour arbitrators to exalt <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m over substanceand facts, the proposed changes make thefacts and realities of the employment relati<strong>on</strong>shipthe key. Employees would no l<strong>on</strong>ger be c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tedwith the dilemma of en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing a c<strong>on</strong>tract wherethe employer has illegally withheld <strong>on</strong>e.Case 12:Out-of-court dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> as apractical tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentFor poor people around the world, getting accessto courts and legal support to protect their rightsis often impossible. In many cases, the reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>this is straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward — they cannot af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d to paythe legal fees. In Tajikistan, the UK has helped tosolve this problem by supporting Third Party Arbitrati<strong>on</strong>Courts. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se courts are an alternative wayof resolving disputes: two sides of a dispute agreeto nominate a third party who they both trust tomediate their disagreement and come to a decisi<strong>on</strong>.Although they operate independently of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal system, decisi<strong>on</strong>s are recognised byTajikistan’s official courts. This means that whereparties do not comply with a decisi<strong>on</strong>, the statecan step in to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce it.Third Party Arbitrati<strong>on</strong> Courts provide poor peoplewith a cheap, fair and accessible way of resolvingdisputes and protecting their rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y areparticularly effective at protecting the rights ofwomen to land and property.Third Party Arbitrati<strong>on</strong> has helped to make legalservices available to 800,000 people in Tajikistan(12 percent of the populati<strong>on</strong>). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> approach hasalso been used successfully in Russia, Kyrgyzstan,Moldova, Ukraine and Georgia. 100Case 13:Revising bidding and procurementpractices in SenegalGovernment can have a direct role to play in expandingopportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sectorthrough affirmative acti<strong>on</strong> to purchase the goodsand services of the sector. In view of the weaknessesof the sector, government must changec<strong>on</strong>tracting procedures, reduce barriers and makegovernment purchases more accessible to thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re should also be improvedchannels of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> between government andthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector so that the government wouldknow what products are available while those inthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal scetor would know what governmentis buying. With regard to simplifying requirements,the following acti<strong>on</strong>s are proposed:• Break large requirements into smaller sizes thatare more manageable by small suppliers.• Simplify bidding procedures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> smaller requirements.• Reassess existing regulati<strong>on</strong>s with a viewto giving priority to internal sourcingof products.• Reassess procedures with a view to ensuringthat payments are made promptly to the suppli-187


er, perhaps even prepaid, to ease the financialrequirements of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector suppliers.• Establish effective c<strong>on</strong>trol systems to ensurethat these affirmative acti<strong>on</strong>s do not compromisethe need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a reas<strong>on</strong>able price, goodquality and timeliness. 101<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Senegalese Government provides an exampleof a proactive policy of c<strong>on</strong>tracting out public infrastructureprojects to small scale c<strong>on</strong>tractors. Biddingprocedures and documents have been substantiallysimplified to permit smaller c<strong>on</strong>tractorsto participate in the bidding process. Bureaucraticdocumentati<strong>on</strong> was also minimised while biddingdocuments now c<strong>on</strong>tain official unit cost estimatesas a guide to the less sophisticated c<strong>on</strong>tractor. Ageneral sessi<strong>on</strong> is held wherein c<strong>on</strong>tractors are in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>medabout the existence of the implementingagency and are apprised of the entire procedure,from the bidding to the awarding and implementati<strong>on</strong>.Simplificati<strong>on</strong> of the process goes as far asmaking the name of the winner very clear in theannouncement, so that even an illiterate c<strong>on</strong>tractor’srepresentative can readily determine who wasawarded the c<strong>on</strong>tract.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>tract that the successful bidder has to signis basic and c<strong>on</strong>tains <strong>on</strong>ly essential elements, withsuperfluous or general c<strong>on</strong>tent removed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> modelc<strong>on</strong>tract used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all such projects is written inlanguage that is understandable to the laypers<strong>on</strong>,avoiding legal jarg<strong>on</strong> and complicated terminology.During the implementati<strong>on</strong> of the c<strong>on</strong>tract, technicalassistance is provided to the awarded c<strong>on</strong>tractorregarding productivity improvement and basicmanagement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> technical assistance programmecomprises the following comp<strong>on</strong>ents: 1) short courses<strong>on</strong> basic management covering recordkeeping,accounting, stock c<strong>on</strong>trol, and sub-project management;2) short courses and <strong>on</strong>-site technical assis-188tance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>tractors’ managers, site supervisorsand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emen to improve technical management ofthe c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> jobs to improve productivity; and3) ad hoc training <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emen and c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>workers <strong>on</strong> specific c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> techniques relatedto the job <strong>on</strong> hand. By its sec<strong>on</strong>d year of operati<strong>on</strong>in 1992, the programme had reached approximately720 individuals representing over 500 firms. 12


Chapter 3 Endnotes1 See Resoluti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerning the promoti<strong>on</strong> of sustainableenterprises, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference, June 2007.2 World Bank, 2002a.3 Anne Trebilcock, 2005.4 Loayza, 2007.5 Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Fundamental Principles and Rights at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>, ILO,1998.6 ‘Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy,’ Report of the Director-General, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference, ILO, Geneva, 2002.7 In 2003, the Internati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>ference of Labour Statisticiansendorsed a statistical framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> measuring in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.8 Alsop and Heinsohn, 2005.9 World Bank 2002b.10 Trebilcock, A., 2006.11 ILO, 1999.12 Loayza and Rigolini ,2006.13 ILO, 2002b.14 Heintz and Pollin, 2003.15 This summary is based <strong>on</strong> recent analyses of available nati<strong>on</strong>aldata (using the indirect measure of estimating in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employmentas the difference between total employment [estimated by labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cesurveys or populati<strong>on</strong> censuses] and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment [estimatedby enterprise surveys or ec<strong>on</strong>omic censuses]) as well as earliersummaries of these analyses in Chen et al 2005. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors of ILO2002 as well as Heintz and Pollin (2003) analysed a comm<strong>on</strong> set ofoffi cial nati<strong>on</strong>al data collected and compiled by Jacques Charmes.16 Nati<strong>on</strong>al labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce data do not capture all <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a variety of reas<strong>on</strong>s. One reas<strong>on</strong> is that some lawfulpaid activities are not declared to public authorities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> extent andcharacteristics of lawful but undeclared work differ widely betweencountries. A 2004 study <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the European <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> found thatundeclared work represented as much as 20 percent of GDP in somesouthern and eastern European countries (‘Undeclared <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in anEnlarged Uni<strong>on</strong>’ 2004.) Of course, criminal activities are also notdeclared to public authorities. But the defi niti<strong>on</strong> of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy used by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> and in this Report excludes criminalactivities.17 See, Hu, A., <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Emergence of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector and theDevelopment of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in China’s Transiti<strong>on</strong>: A HistoricalPerspective (1952-2004) —(pdf versi<strong>on</strong>, slide 4) Available: http://ccs.tinghua.edu.cn and http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTDECABCTOK2006/Resources/H_Angang.ppt18 In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal wage employment is comprised of employees ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises as well as various types of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal wage workerswho work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises, households, or no fi xed employer.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se include casual day labourers, domestic workers, industrialoutworkers (notably homeworkers), undeclared workers, and part-timeor temporary workers without secure c<strong>on</strong>tracts, worker benefi ts, orsocial protecti<strong>on</strong>.19 Chen et al., 2005.20 Analysis of nati<strong>on</strong>al data by Jacques Charmes, cited in Chen etal., 2005.21 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se fi gures were computed by Jeemol Unni using the individualrecords of the Employment and Unemployment Survey, 1999-2000,55th Round of the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Sample Survey Organisati<strong>on</strong>, New Delhi.22 Heintz ,2006.23 Loayza and Rigolini, 2006. For fi gures <strong>on</strong> China, also see Hu,Angang, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Emergence of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector and the Developmentof In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in China’s Transiti<strong>on</strong>: A Historical Perspective(1952-2004). Available: http://ccs.tinghua.edu.cnand at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTDECABCTOK2006/Resources/H_Angang.ppt24 Chen et al. 2005.25 Heintz 2006. Blunch et al. 2001.26 Statisticians distinguish three main sub-categories of selfemployment:1) ‘employers’, the self-employed who hire others; 2)‘own account workers’, who do not hire others; 2’; and 3) ‘unpaidc<strong>on</strong>tributing family workers’. However, many statistical analyses,such as those by the OECD reported by Carré 2006, exclude unpaidfamily members because they are c<strong>on</strong>sidered ‘assistants’, not‘entrepreneurs’. Since the majority of unpaid family workers in mostc<strong>on</strong>texts are women, this exclusi<strong>on</strong> understates the real level ofwomen’s labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce participati<strong>on</strong> and entrepreneurship (Carré 2006).27 UNRISD 2005, Heintz 200528 Heintz 2005.29 ibid.30 Chen et al 2005.31 Carré 2006:1332 Ibid.33 Tomei 2005.34 ILO 2003b.35 Based <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cepti<strong>on</strong> provided by the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Rapporteur,Martinez-Cobo, in the Study <strong>on</strong> the Problem of Discriminati<strong>on</strong> againstIndigenous Populati<strong>on</strong>s. Cited in Tomei 2005.36 Tomei, 2005.37 ibid.38 Chen 2006b.39 Article I of the Declarati<strong>on</strong> of Philadelphia, Internati<strong>on</strong>al LabourC<strong>on</strong>ference, 1944, Annex to the C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> of the Internati<strong>on</strong>al LabourOrganisati<strong>on</strong>.40 ILO 2006.41 Although a number of ILO labour standards addressed workersoutside of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy (e.g., indigenous and tribal peoples,rural workers, etc.) since the 1960s, these did not previously result ininternati<strong>on</strong>al policy c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> as a growingglobal trend.42 Stiglitz 2001.43 ILO 2002b.44 Freeman 1996.45 Tokman 2007a.46 Anne Trebilcock 2004.47 Paragraph 47 of the 2005 Summit Outcome Document.189


48 Including the UN funds, programmes and agencies, regi<strong>on</strong>alec<strong>on</strong>omic commissi<strong>on</strong>s and development banks, as well as theinternati<strong>on</strong>al fi nancial instituti<strong>on</strong>s and the World Trade Organisati<strong>on</strong>(WTO)49 Summit Outcome Document, ECOSOC 2006 Declarati<strong>on</strong>.50 See Marty Chen, ‘<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor: Process andOutcomes’, Harvard, July 20, 2007.5152 This could be guided by the Employment Relati<strong>on</strong>shipRecommendati<strong>on</strong>s, 2006, adopted by the 91st sessi<strong>on</strong> of theInternati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference.53 Chile adopted a new law in 2006 to regulate thesearrangements, allocating solidarity resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities to sub-c<strong>on</strong>tractorand subc<strong>on</strong>tracting fi rms involved. It also introduced the right ofthe latter to c<strong>on</strong>trol the compliance of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer and to c<strong>on</strong>vert itsresp<strong>on</strong>sibility into subsidiary. It also adapted the Labour Inspecti<strong>on</strong> tobe able to certify the degree of en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement <strong>on</strong> line and up dated.54 See V. Tokman, “In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, insecurity and social cohesi<strong>on</strong> inLatin America’, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Review, vol. 126 (2007), number1-2, ILO, Geneva. In Bogota, Colombia a survey of micro enterprisesindicates that 76 percent am<strong>on</strong>g them could not pay all the labourc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s required by law, and in Lima, Peru this percentagereached to 85 percent.55 ILO, ‘Business envir<strong>on</strong>ment, labour law and micro and smallenterprises’, Committee <strong>on</strong> Employment and Social Policy, GoverningBody 297th sessi<strong>on</strong>, Geneva, 2006. Another specifi c experience is thechange of pecuniary sancti<strong>on</strong>s by using the resources <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improvingthe knowledge of micro-entrepreneurs <strong>on</strong> their obligati<strong>on</strong>s in Chile.Although ignorance cannot be claimed as an excuse <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> lack ofcompliance, there is need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> support when levels of educati<strong>on</strong> are lowand access to costly professi<strong>on</strong>al services cannot be af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ded.56 See Resoluti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerning the promoti<strong>on</strong> of sustainableenterprises, 96th Sessi<strong>on</strong> of the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference, June2007.57 See Case 6, annexed to this chapter.58 See Case 7.59 World Bank, ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality: Exit and Exclusi<strong>on</strong>’, Washingt<strong>on</strong> , 2007.60 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> public funds involved are the highest in Bolivia (1,2percentof GNP) and are estimated <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the quasi-universal pensi<strong>on</strong> of Chile at1,0 percent compared to the focused pensi<strong>on</strong>s in the Regi<strong>on</strong> that areusually below 0,5 percent of GNP.61 See Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference, Resoluti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> theemployment relati<strong>on</strong>ship, Geneva, 2006.62 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> current, dominant rubric <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> understanding and analysingthe impact of regulati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth is through the use ofmulti-country surveys, whose core functi<strong>on</strong> is to provide measuresof the costs of business regulati<strong>on</strong> within an ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se multicountrysurveys have, over a fairly short space of time, come todominate global, regi<strong>on</strong>al and country-level policy discussi<strong>on</strong>s aroundthe potential ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>sequences of labour market regulati<strong>on</strong>.Two of these surveys loom large <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> analytical work <strong>on</strong> the developingworld, namely the Investment Climate Assessment (ICA) surveys andthe Doing Business Survey (DBS) — both run under the auspices ofthe World Bank. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ICA measures fi rms’ percepti<strong>on</strong>s of the investmentclimate in their country and are based <strong>on</strong> a standard core module(See http://rru.worldbank.org/InvestmentClimate/About.aspx <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thisstandard questi<strong>on</strong>naire). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong>naire covers senior manager’spercepti<strong>on</strong>s of obstacles to growth and investment, as well asin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> fi rm per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> data is organised accordingto a series of topics including infrastructure and services; fi nance;government policies and services; labour relati<strong>on</strong>s and innovati<strong>on</strong>(World Bank, 2007). Currently the ICA includes data <strong>on</strong> 58 countries(World Bank, 2007). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Doing Business Survey (DBS) has been<strong>on</strong>going since 2004, and in the most recent round in 2007, coveredclose to 180 countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> DBS deals with issues such as c<strong>on</strong>tracten<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement; property rights regulati<strong>on</strong>; business licensing and ofparticular interest to us here — labour market regulati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> methodof data collecti<strong>on</strong> is a combinati<strong>on</strong> of studying individual country lawsand regulati<strong>on</strong>s and surveys of local lawyers.63 For further background <strong>on</strong> these questi<strong>on</strong>s, see Berg and Kucera(eds.), In Defence of Labour Market Instituti<strong>on</strong>s: Cultivating Justice inthe Developing World (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>thcoming).64 Botero et al (2004) undertook a seminal study <strong>on</strong> the impact oflabour regulati<strong>on</strong> around the world. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> data covers 85 countries andis very deliberate in its c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> of indices of labour regulati<strong>on</strong>ranging from, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, laws <strong>on</strong> overtime and part-time work tothose <strong>on</strong> dismissals, notice periods and the right to strike activity andcollective bargaining. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> is representative of countrylevelin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the late 1990s, and in most cases refl ects data<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1997. It was, as far is known, the fi rst exhaustive, comprehensivemeasure of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> that is cross-country in nature and notpercepti<strong>on</strong>-based.65 Botero et al (2004), p. 1364, shows that of all the labourregulati<strong>on</strong> measures, <strong>on</strong>ly dismissal procedures in their cross-countryregressi<strong>on</strong>s are a signifi cant and negative determinant of the logof GNP per capita, while social security provisi<strong>on</strong>s are positivelyassociated with growth.66 ILO Governing Body ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> United Nati<strong>on</strong>s and Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m’ 300thSessi<strong>on</strong> Geneva, November 2007 GB.300/4/167 Mal<strong>on</strong>ey 2003.68 McKinesey Quarterly, ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> hidden dangers of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy.’69 IOE 2006.70 OECD 2006.71 Nickell and Layard 1998; and Levine and Tys<strong>on</strong> 1990.72 Gregg and Manning 1997.73 Saavedra and Torero 2004.74 Kugler et al. 2003.75 Acemoglu and Angrist 200176 In the case of Sara, et al., vs. Agarrado, et al. G.R. No. 73199, 26October 1988.77 See ILO,’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy: enabling transiti<strong>on</strong> to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>,’ Tripartite Interregi<strong>on</strong>al Symposium <strong>on</strong> the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy, Geneva, November 2007.78 See also C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> 156, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers with Family Resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities.79 No. 177, 1966.80 See Annex 1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> more details.81 See Resoluti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerning the promoti<strong>on</strong> of sustainableenterprises, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference, June 2007.82 Thanachaisethavut and Charoenlert 2006.190


83 Boundary: a cab driver, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, pays a fi xed amount to theowner <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the use of the vehicle, retaining the fares above this amount<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> his expenses and keeping the balance as his actual earnings.84 In the case of Sara, et al., vs. Agarrado, et al. G.R. No. 73199, 26October 1988.85 Chen 2006c.86 As in other minimum wage negotiati<strong>on</strong>s, SEWA seeks to havethe minimum wage fi xed in a tripartite negotiati<strong>on</strong> with the Labour<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>er’s Offi ce, the employer, and the workers so it will beacceptable to all c<strong>on</strong>cerned. Also, SEWA does not expect that theminimum wage will be en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced but uses it as a benchmark or targetin <strong>on</strong>-going negotiati<strong>on</strong>s.87 Yu, S. and Karaos, A. 2004; UN-Habitat 2006.88 Chen 2006d.89 As noted earlier, ‘unorganised worker’ is the term used in India<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> workers in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment and does not imply that suchworkers are not organised into uni<strong>on</strong>s or other organisati<strong>on</strong>s90 Previously, the defi niti<strong>on</strong> of the regular self-employed waslimited <strong>on</strong>ly to ‘all self-employed professi<strong>on</strong>als, partners and singleproprietors of businesses, actors and actresses, directors, scriptwritersand news corresp<strong>on</strong>dents, who do not fall within the defi niti<strong>on</strong> of theterm ‘employee,’ professi<strong>on</strong>al athletes, coaches, trainers and jockeys’(Secti<strong>on</strong> 9-A, Social Security Act of 1997). Under the new resoluti<strong>on</strong>,the defi niti<strong>on</strong> of self-employed has now been expanded to include lowincome earners.91 Government White Paper, 2004 at: http://www.china.org.cn/e-white/20040907/8.htm92 Tokman 2006.93 Larss<strong>on</strong> 2006.94 Estrada, and Izquierdo 2002.95 Guell-Rotllan and Petr<strong>on</strong>golo 2000.96 Dorantes, 2000.97 ‘China to train 60 milli<strong>on</strong> rural labourers be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e 2010’ in People’sDaily at : http//english.peopledaily.com.cn/200309/27/eng20030927_125088.shtml98 Wen Jiabao, Report of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> of the Government. Delivered atthe Fourth Sessi<strong>on</strong> of the Tenth Nati<strong>on</strong>al People’s C<strong>on</strong>gress. 5 March2006. Available: http://big5.xinhuanet.com/gate/big5/news.xinhuanet.com/english/2006-03/14/c<strong>on</strong>tent_4303943.htm99 ibid.100 DFID, 2006.101 Griers<strong>on</strong> and Mead 1995.102 Pean and Wats<strong>on</strong> 1993.Chapter 3 BibliographyAcemoglu, D and J Angrist (2001) ‘C<strong>on</strong>sequences of EmploymentProtecti<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case of the Americans with Disability Act’Journal of Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, Vol. 109, October 2001.Ahmed, S and S.Devarajan (2007) Labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s: To Create Good Jobs,Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s.Oped. Special to <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Times, India.Ahsan, A. and C. Pagés (2007) Are all Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s Equal?Assessing the Effects of Job Security. Labour Dispute andC<strong>on</strong>tract Labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in India. SP Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No.0713. Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> Discussi<strong>on</strong> Papers. World Bank:Washingt<strong>on</strong>.R. Alsop and Heinsohn, 2005. Measuring Empowerment in Practice:Structuring Analysis and Framing Indicators. World BankPolicy Research <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper No. 3510. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC,World Bank, Feb.Amuedo-Dorantes, C., 2000. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> transiti<strong>on</strong>s into and out ofinvoluntary temporary employment in a segmented market:evidence from Spain.’ Industrial and Labour Relati<strong>on</strong>sReview, Vol. 53, Issue 2. pp. 309-325.Barrientos, A., D. Hulme and A. Shepherd. 2004. ‘Can Social Protecti<strong>on</strong>Tackle Chr<strong>on</strong>ic Poverty?’ Background paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theC<strong>on</strong>ference ‘Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chr<strong>on</strong>ic Poverty - Risk,Needs and Rights — Protecting What? How?’ IDPM/University of Manchester, 23-24 February 2005.Besley,T. and R.Burgess. 2004. ‘Can Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s HinderEc<strong>on</strong>omic Per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance? Evidence from India.’ QuarterlyJournal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics. February. 91-134.Bhorat, Haro<strong>on</strong>. 2007. ‘Debates <strong>on</strong> Labour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s as a Cost ofDoing Business.’ Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the UN <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.Blunch, Niels-Hugo, Sudharshan Canagarajah, and Dhushyanth Raju.2001. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector Revisited: A Synthesis AcrossSpace and Time.’ Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No.0119. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank, July.Botero, J.C., S.Djankov, R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes and A. Shleifer.2004. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Regulati<strong>on</strong> of Labour.’ Quarterly Journal ofEc<strong>on</strong>omics. November. 1339-1382.Carré, Françoise and Joaquin Herranz, Jr. 2002. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Jobs inIndustrialized ‘North’ Countries.’ Background paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Women and Men in In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Employment: A StatisticalPicture.Charmes, J. 2000. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector to GDP inDeveloping Countries: Assessment, Estimates, Methods,Orientati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Future.’ Paper presented at the FourthMeeting of the Expert Group <strong>on</strong> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector Statistics(Delhi Group), Geneva, 28-30 August 2000.Chen, M. 2007. ‘Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Mismatch: Formal Instituti<strong>on</strong>s andIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Realities.’ Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. May 19._______. 2006a. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of Labour Markets : Is Formalizati<strong>on</strong>the Answer ?’ Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor, November._______. 2006b. ‘Rethinking the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: Linkages with191


the Formal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Regulatory Envir<strong>on</strong>ment.’In B. Guha-Khasnobis, R. Kanbur, E. Ostrom (ed.), Linkingthe Formal and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: C<strong>on</strong>cepts and Measures.Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d: Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d University Press._______. 2006c. ‘Empowerment of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers: <strong>Legal</strong> andOther Interventi<strong>on</strong>s.’ Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. 15December._______. 2006d. ‘Empowerment of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers: <strong>Legal</strong> andOther Interventi<strong>on</strong>s.’ Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. 16December.Chen, M., J. Vanek, F. Lund, J. Heintz, R. Jhabvala and C. B<strong>on</strong>ner. 2005.Progress of the World’s Women 2005: Women, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>, andPoverty. New York: UNIFEM.Coase, R.H. 1937. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> nature of the fi rm.’ Ec<strong>on</strong>omica (NS), 4: 386-405. As cited in Deakin 2004.Co<strong>on</strong>ey, Sean, Tim Lindsey, Richard Mitchell and Zhu, Ying. 2002. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>and Labour Market Regulati<strong>on</strong> in South East Asia. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>:Routledge.Deakin, Sim<strong>on</strong>. 2004. ‘Renewing labour market instituti<strong>on</strong>s.’ ILO SocialPolicy Lectures. Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> LabourStudies.Department <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development (DFID). 2006. ‘EliminatingWorld Poverty: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> governance work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor.’ Awhite paper <strong>on</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>al development. Presented toParliament by the Secretary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development._______. 2004. ‘Labour Standards and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>.’Deyo, F.C.1989. Beneath the Miracle: Labour Subordinati<strong>on</strong> in the NewAsian Industrialism. Berkeley: University of Cali<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>niaPress.Dolado, J.J., et al. (1999), ‘Los problemas del mercado de trabajoen España: Empleo, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mación y salarios mínimos.’Ek<strong>on</strong>omiaz, Vol. 43.Dolado, J., F. Kramarz, S. Machin, A. Manning, D. Margolis, and C.Teulings. 1998. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Impact of Minimum Wagesin Europe.’ Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Policy 23: 319-372.Dolado, J. J., C. García-Serrano, and J.F. Jimeno. 2002. ‘DrawingLess<strong>on</strong>s from the Boom of Temporary Jobs in Spain.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal, Vol. 112, F270-F295.Elliot, K.A., and R. Freeman. 2003. ‘Can labour standards improveunder globalizati<strong>on</strong>?’ Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC.Estrada, A., P. Garcia-Perea and M. Izquierdo. 2002. ‘Los fl ujos detrabajadores en Espana: el impacto del empleo temporal.’Documento de Trabajo 02026, Banco de Espana.Forteza, Alvaro and Martín Rama. 2001, ‘Labour Market Rigidity andthe Success of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms across more than 100Countries.’ mimeo. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank: Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC.Freeman, Richard. 1996. ‘Internati<strong>on</strong>al labour standards and worldtrade: Friends or foes?’ In: Schott, Jeffrey J. (ed.), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> WorldTrading System: Challenges Ahead. Washingt<strong>on</strong>: Institute<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omics.Galli, Rossana and David Kucera. 2004. ‘Labour Standards andIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Employment in Latin America.’ World DevelopmentVol. 32. (5)Gregg, P., and A. Manning. 1997. ‘Labour Market Regulati<strong>on</strong> andUnemployment.’ In Snower, D. and de la Dehesa, G. (eds.),Unemployment Policy: Government Opti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the LabourMarket. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Griers<strong>on</strong>, John, and D<strong>on</strong>ald Mead. 1995. ‘Business Linkages inZimbabwe: C<strong>on</strong>cept, Practice and Strategies.’ GEMINI<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper No. 50. PACT Publicati<strong>on</strong>s, USA.Guell-Rotllan, G., and B. Petr<strong>on</strong>golo. 2000. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’ transiti<strong>on</strong> fromtemporary to permanent employment: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Spanish case.’Centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong> School ofEc<strong>on</strong>omics and Political Science, Discussi<strong>on</strong> paper 438.Heckman, J and C. Pagés. 2003. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Employment: Less<strong>on</strong>s fromLatin America and the Caribbean.’ NBER <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper10129 . www.nber.org/papers/w10129Heintz, J. 2006. ‘Growth, Employment, and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>.’Discussi<strong>on</strong> paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the workshop ‘Growth,Employment, and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>,’ held at theDepartment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development, 17 March 2006._______. 2005. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Growing In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality of Labour Markets.’ Paperpresented at the UNRISD/CGGS C<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> Gender andSocial Policy, Marstrand, Sweden, 28-29 May._______, and Robert Pollin. 2003. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>, ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth,and the challenge of creating viable labour standards indeveloping countries.’ PERI <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper, No. 60, Amherst,MA: Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Research Institute.Heintz, J. 2002. ‘Global Labour Standards: their impact andimplementati<strong>on</strong>.’ PERI <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper 46. MA: University ofMassachusetts Amherst.McKinsey. 2004. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Hidden Dangers of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy.’McKinsey Quarterly, (3).Huds<strong>on</strong>, Ken. 1999. ‘No shortage of ‘n<strong>on</strong>standard’ jobs.’ Ec<strong>on</strong>omicPolicy Institute Briefi ng Paper. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C.Hussmanns, Ralf. 2004. ‘Defi ning and measuring in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malemployment.’ Geneva, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Organisati<strong>on</strong> (ILO). 2007. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> United Nati<strong>on</strong>sand Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m’ ILO Governing Body, 300 th Sessi<strong>on</strong>, GB.300/4/1Geneva, November 2007_______. 2007. ‘Global Employment Trends 2007: Brief January2007.’_______. 2006. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, Poverty and Employment: GoodPractices and Less<strong>on</strong>s Learned.’ Bangkok: ILO Subregi<strong>on</strong>alOffi ce <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> East Asia, 2006_______. 2005. ‘World Employment Report 2004-05: EmploymentProductivity and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>.’ Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>alLabour Organisati<strong>on</strong>._______. 2003a. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing out of Poverty.’ Report of the Director-General. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference 91 st Sessi<strong>on</strong>2003. Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce._______. 2003b. ‘ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Indigenous and Tribal Peoples,1989.’ (No. 169): A Manual. Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>al LabourOffi ce._______. 2003c. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Employment Relati<strong>on</strong>ship: An annotated guideto ILO Recommendati<strong>on</strong> No. 198.’ Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>alLabour Offi ce.192


_______. 2002a. ‘Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy.’ Report ofthe Director-General, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference, ILO,Geneva, 2002._______. 2002b. ‘Women and Men in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy : AStatistical Picture.’ Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce._______. 1999. Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Report of the Director General to the87 th Sessi<strong>on</strong> of the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference.Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce.Kucera, David. 2004. ‘Core Labour Standards and Ec<strong>on</strong>omicDevelopment,’ Labour History, Vol. 45 (4)_______. 2001. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> effects of core workers rights <strong>on</strong> labour costsand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign direct investment: evaluating the ‘c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>alwisdom.’ ‘ Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Research Program Discussi<strong>on</strong>Paper, No. 130, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Labour Studies,Geneva.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Organisati<strong>on</strong> of Employers (IOE). 2006. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy — <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Employers’ Approach.’ November.J<strong>on</strong>ge, Alice de. 2004. ‘Global Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Forces and Individual LabourRights: An Uneasy Coexistence.’ Human Rights and HumanWelfare. Volume 4 (1) University of Denver.Kugler, A., J. F. Jimeno, and V. Hernanz. 2003. ‘EmploymentC<strong>on</strong>sequences of Restrictive Permanent C<strong>on</strong>tracts:Evidence from Spanish Labour Market Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.’ CEPRDiscussi<strong>on</strong> Papers 3724.Kuruvilla 1995 in Co<strong>on</strong>ey. (fi nd publicati<strong>on</strong> info)Lazear, E. 1990. ‘Job Security Provisi<strong>on</strong>s and Employment.’ QuarterlyJournal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics. August. 699-726.Larss<strong>on</strong>, Allan. 2006. ‘Flexibility at the margin: Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of the labourmarket in Spain .’ Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.Lecuyer, Normand and Jean Courdouan, eds. 2002. ‘New <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms oflabour administrati<strong>on</strong>: Actors in development.’ Geneva:Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce.Levine, D.I.,. and L.D.A. Tys<strong>on</strong>. 1990. ‘Participati<strong>on</strong>, Productivity andthe Firm’s Envir<strong>on</strong>ment.’ In Blinder, A. (ed.). Paying <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Productivity. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: Brookings Instituti<strong>on</strong>.Lim, Lim. 2003. ‘Highlights of the ILC C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s.’ Presented at theTurin <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>shop <strong>on</strong> the Follow-up to the ILC C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, ILO Internati<strong>on</strong>alTraining Centre, Turin, 10-12 Feb.Loayza,N., A.M.Oviedo and L.Serven. (2005) ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact of Regulati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> Growth and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector: Cross CountryEvidence.’ Unpublished mimeo. World Bank: Washingt<strong>on</strong>DC.Loayza, N., A..M.Oviedo and L.Serven. 2007. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact of regulati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> growth and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality: cross-country evidence. Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dUniversity Press.Loayza, N. and J. Rigolini. 2006. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality Trends and Cycles.’ WorldBank Policy Research <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper Series 4078, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> WorldBank.Mal<strong>on</strong>ey, William. 2003. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality revisited.’ World Bank PolicyResearch <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper Series 2965, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank.Manning, Chris. 2004. ‘Legislating <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Labour Protecti<strong>on</strong> : Betting<strong>on</strong> the Weak or the Str<strong>on</strong>g?’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper 2004/08. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Australian Nati<strong>on</strong>al University, Divisi<strong>on</strong> of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,December.Marsden, D. 1999a. ‘Breaking the link. Has the employment c<strong>on</strong>tracthad its day?’ Centrepiece, 1999, winter, 20-23. As cited inDeakin 2004.M<strong>on</strong>tenegro, C. and C. Pagés. 2003. ‘Who Benefi ts from Labour MarketRegulati<strong>on</strong>s? Chile 1960-1998.’ NBER <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper 9850.Morin, Marie-Laure. 2005. ‘Labour law and new <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of corporateorganisati<strong>on</strong>.’ Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Review, Volume 144, (1)Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce.Murthi, Mamta, Michael J. Orszag, and Peter R. Orszag. 1999. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>charge ratio <strong>on</strong> individual accounts: Less<strong>on</strong>s from the U.K.experience.’ Birbeck College <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper 99-2. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>,University of L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>, March.Narayan, D., R. Patel, K. Schaftt, A. Rademacher, and S. Koch-Schulte.1999. Can any<strong>on</strong>e hear us? Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC, World Bank.Nati<strong>on</strong>al Statistics Offi ce. 1995. ‘1995 Urban In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector Survey inMetro Manila: Highlights of Findings.’ Nati<strong>on</strong>al StatisticsOffi ce.Nati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Development and Labour Council (NEDLAC) 2006.‘Impact of Labour Market Policy <strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy:Analysis and Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s.’ A NEDLAC CommunityC<strong>on</strong>stituency Paper. 26 June.Nickell, S. and R. Layard. 1998. ‘Labour Market Instituti<strong>on</strong>s andEc<strong>on</strong>omic Per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance.’ In Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D.(eds.) Handbook of Labour Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, Vol. 3C. Amsterdam:North Holland.North, Douglass. 1989. ‘Instituti<strong>on</strong>s and ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth: Anhistorical introducti<strong>on</strong>.’ World Development Vol. 17 (9):1319-1332.Organisati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Cooperati<strong>on</strong> and Development (OECD).2006. ‘OECD Employment Outlook,’ www.oecd.org.____. 2000. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Trade and Core Labour Standards. Paris____. 1995a. Trade and Labour Standards: Report <strong>on</strong> a meetingof trade uni<strong>on</strong> experts held under the OECD Labour/Management Program. Paris: OECD.____. 1995b. Trade and Labour Standards: A Review of the Issues.Paris: OECD.Pean, Leslie and Peter Wats<strong>on</strong>. 1993. ‘Promoti<strong>on</strong> of small-scaleenterprises in Senegal’s building and c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> sector:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘AGETIP’ experience.’ In Helmsing and Kolstee, 1993.Pradhan, B. K, P.K. Roy, and M.R. Saluja. 1999. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sectorin India: A Study of Household Saving Behaviour.’C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector to the Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, ReportNo. 1. New Delhi: Nati<strong>on</strong>al Council of Applied Ec<strong>on</strong>omicResearch.Ranis, Gustav. 1995. ‘Another Look at the East Asian Miracle.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>World Bank Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp. 509-534.Roaring, Elena. 2003. ‘Government Regulatory System and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector.’In Yu, Sandra (ed.). Challenge of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the Philippines.Manila: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Office.Saavedra, J. and M. Torero. 2004. ‘Labour Market Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms and <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>irImpact over Formal Labour Demand and Job MarketTurnover: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case of Peru.’ In Heckman J. J. and C. Pagés(eds.). <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Employment. Less<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Latin Americaand the Caribbean. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: University of Chicago Press:193


131—182.Sabel, C., D. O’Rourke, and A. Fung. 2000. ‘Ratcheting LabourStandards: Regulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>tinuous Improvement in theGlobal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>place.’ 23 February draft.Sator, Vanessa and Marilou Renales. 2003. ‘Improving <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ingC<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector.’ In Yu, Sandra, ed.,Challenge of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the Philippines. Manila:Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce.Sengenberger, Werner. 2005. ‘Globalizati<strong>on</strong> and Social Progress: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Role and Impact of Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Standards.’Sec<strong>on</strong>d revised and extended versi<strong>on</strong>. B<strong>on</strong>n: Friedrich EbertStiftung, September.Sethuraman, S. V. (1997) ‘Urban Poverty, and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector: ACritical Assessment of Current Strategies.’ Available fromILO at http://www.ilo.org/public/english/employment/rec<strong>on</strong>/eiip/publ/1998/urbpover.htmSingh, N. 2003. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Impact of Internati<strong>on</strong>al Standards : A Survey ofEc<strong>on</strong>omic <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory.’ in K. Basu, H. Horn, L. Roman and J.Shapiro (eds.) Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Standards, Blackwell,Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d.Stiglitz, J. 2001. ‘Employment, Social Justice, and Societal Well-Being.’Keynote Speech to the ILO Global Employment Forum, 1-3November, ILO Geneva.Sudharshan C. and S.V. Sethuraman. 2001. ‘Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> and theIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector in Developing Countries: Challenges andOpportunities.’ Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper Series.Washingt<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank. December.Sugden, Robert. 1998. ‘Sp<strong>on</strong>taneous order.’ Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omicPerspectives, 3: 85-97.Tajgman, David. 2006. ‘Extending labour law to all workers: promotingdecent work in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy in Cambodia,Thailand and M<strong>on</strong>golia.’ Bangkok: Internati<strong>on</strong>al LabourOffi ce.Thanachaisethavut, B and V. Charoenlert. 2006. ‘Extending LabourProtecti<strong>on</strong> to the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in Thailand.’ In DavidTagjman (ed.), Extending Labour Protecti<strong>on</strong> to All <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers:Promoting Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy inCambodia, Thailand and M<strong>on</strong>golia. Bangkok: Internati<strong>on</strong>alLabour Offi ce.Tokman, Victor. 2006. ‘Chile: A promising design towards the legalempowerment of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.’ Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor.____. 2007a. ‘<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment Policies: On Labour Rights.’ Paperprepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> of <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor. May.____. 2007b. ‘From In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality to Modernizati<strong>on</strong>.’ In Towards Full andDecent Employment. L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Zed Books and Hyderabad:Orient L<strong>on</strong>gman and Penang: Third World Network, inassociati<strong>on</strong> with the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s, New York:Tomei, Manuela. 2005. Indigenous and tribal peoples: An ethnic auditof selected Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong> Strategy Papers. Geneva:Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce.Trebilcock, Anne. 2006. ‘Using Development Approaches to Addressthe Challenge of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>.’ InDavidov, G and B. Lagnille (eds.), Boundaries and Fr<strong>on</strong>tiersof Labor <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>: Goals and Means in the Regulati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Oreg<strong>on</strong>: Hart.____. 2005. ‘Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy.’ Discussi<strong>on</strong>Paper No 2005/04, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki.____, 2004. ‘Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Standards and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy.’ In Les normes internati<strong>on</strong>ales du travail: unpatrimoine pour l’avenir. Mélanges en l’h<strong>on</strong>neur de NicolasValticos. Geneva: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Organisati<strong>on</strong>. 585-613UN-Habitat. 2006. Analytical Perspective of Pro-poor Slum UpgradingFrameworks. Nairobi, UN-Habitat and Cities Alliance.February.United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Research Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Social Development (UNRISD).2005. Gender Equality: Striving <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Justice in an UnequalWorld. New York: UNRISD.Viénot, M. 1995. « Rapport sur le C<strong>on</strong>seil d’Administrati<strong>on</strong> des Sociétéscotées. » Revue de Droit des Affaires Internati<strong>on</strong>ales 8:372.Wailes, Nick. 2002. ‘Globalizati<strong>on</strong> and Nati<strong>on</strong>al Patterns of IndustrialRelati<strong>on</strong>s: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case of Australia,’ in Roger Blanpain (ed),‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Impact of Globalizati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Employment Relati<strong>on</strong>s: AComparis<strong>on</strong> of the Automobile and Banking Industries inAustralia and Korea.’ Published in a special issue of theBulletin of Labour Relati<strong>on</strong>s, Vol. 45.World Bank. 2005. Doing Business in 2005: Removing Obstacles toGrowth. An Overview. World Bank, Internati<strong>on</strong>al FinanceCorporati<strong>on</strong> and Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d University Press.__________. 2007. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality: Exit and Exclusi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank,2007.World Bank. 2007. ‘Enterprise Surveys Online Database.’ http://www.enterprisesurveys.org/__________. 2005. A Better Investment Climate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Every<strong>on</strong>e</str<strong>on</strong>g>, 2005World Development Report. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank.__________. 2002a. Voices of the Poor. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.__________. 2002b. ‘Empowerment and Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>: ASourcebook.’ World Bank, 2002. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC. http://go.worldbank.org/FD9HH8DH11W__________. 2001. World Development Report 2000/2001: AttackingPoverty. Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.Yu, S. and A. Karaos. 2004. ‘Establishing the role of communitiesin governance: the experience of the Homeless People’sFederati<strong>on</strong> Philippines.’ Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> and Envir<strong>on</strong>ment. Vol.16 No. 1, April.194


ChapterFOURBusiness Rights195


EXECUTIVE SUMMARY‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> opposite of poverty is not wealth — it is justice. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> objective…is to create a more just society,not necessarily a wealthier <strong>on</strong>e. And the great questi<strong>on</strong> is how do we do this?’Le<strong>on</strong>ardo Boff, Franciscan <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ologian, Brazil<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> is central to our lives. Earning alivelihood is not <strong>on</strong>ly a basic need,it is a requirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> enriching oursense of well-being and the quality of life in general.Underpinning a system that c<strong>on</strong>tributes toemployment generati<strong>on</strong> and to the ability to earna living are the savings, investment and innovati<strong>on</strong>undertaken largely by businesses. 1Persistent poverty is the result of both publicpolicy failure and market failure. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> two arerelated as prevalent policies and the resultingsystem of governance, instituti<strong>on</strong>al structure andlegal rights tend to characterise and limit thefuncti<strong>on</strong> of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy, markets and businesses,and define what they can do and what theyare allowed to do.This report attempts to outline how legal mechanismscan empower milli<strong>on</strong>s of working poor whoapply initiative and entrepreneurship to earn theirliving in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector of ec<strong>on</strong>omies acrossthe world. It begins by outlining the barriers thatentrepreneurs face in accessing opportunities inthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omic system. Case studies arepresented to illustrate some soluti<strong>on</strong>s and innovati<strong>on</strong>s;they are intended to be studied, adaptedand scaled up. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> report c<strong>on</strong>cludes by underliningessential principles and key c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s inmoving re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m fr<strong>on</strong>tiers towards more inclusive,gender resp<strong>on</strong>sive and integrated ec<strong>on</strong>omies.After examining current policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in privatesector development as well as innovati<strong>on</strong> in instituti<strong>on</strong>aldesign and business linkages, our workinggroup <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter c<strong>on</strong>cluded that legalempowerment of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses can serveto promote rights-based ec<strong>on</strong>omic empowerment.<strong>Legal</strong> recogniti<strong>on</strong> of labour and commercial rightsof business and its incorporati<strong>on</strong> into governanceinstituti<strong>on</strong>s should be at the core of legal mechanismsto empower in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal business.Productivity and protecti<strong>on</strong> can and should bepromoted together. This two-pr<strong>on</strong>ged approachcould help to remove barriers in the wider legal/regulatory/market envir<strong>on</strong>ment; it could do this bychanging or simplifying registrati<strong>on</strong> and licensingprocedures and extending greater legal rights tothe working poor. This would serve to empowerthe working poor to know and demand their legalrights, negotiate with officials, bargain more effectivelyin market transacti<strong>on</strong>s, and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce c<strong>on</strong>tractsor seek redress when c<strong>on</strong>tracts are violated.It would also permit them to be represented inrelevant policymaking and rule-setting bodies.196


In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses are inextricablylinked. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are a variety of reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> lack ofadherence to legal and regulatory requirementsby in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses. N<strong>on</strong>-compliance meansgreater profits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses, or it couldbe that the requirements are irrelevant, inappropriate,or n<strong>on</strong>-existent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses.Possibly, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses cannot af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d tocomply with the regulati<strong>on</strong>s. Also, many do notknow what is required, or they may be unsureas to what advantages there could be under‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal’ status. Because of the uncertainties,in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses c<strong>on</strong>tinue to chart out <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>their own operati<strong>on</strong>al support, building networksand in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal c<strong>on</strong>tractual arrangements groundedmore <strong>on</strong> social mores than <strong>on</strong> any legal basis.<strong>Legal</strong>, policy and regulatory re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and innovati<strong>on</strong>,derived from what works <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor andwhat would guarantee their fundamental rights,is l<strong>on</strong>g overdue. Milli<strong>on</strong>s of working poor men andwomen have no knowledge of what rights theyare guaranteed under nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>allaw, or of government obligati<strong>on</strong>s to provide orfacilitate infrastructure, as well as financial,technical, and business services. With support ofcivil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s, or through their ownassociati<strong>on</strong>s, they are beginning to demand some<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of legal identity or protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themselvesand their livelihood activities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>se is a re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m agenda that prioritisesapproaches to achieving the objectives,and determines the order in which the selectedmeasures are to be introduced. This would serveto optimise the productive potential of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malentrepreneurs and facilitate the protecti<strong>on</strong> oftheir businesses. As <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the objectives, they arebroadly listed as follows: reducing regulatoryburdens; removing unnecessary barriers to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malmarkets and instituti<strong>on</strong>s; increasing opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business linkages; increasing benefits andprotecti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector;strengthening the organisati<strong>on</strong> and representati<strong>on</strong>of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs, and providingequal access of working poor women and men toall of the above.Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, improvement in the quality of instituti<strong>on</strong>sin an ec<strong>on</strong>omy has to proceed simultaneouslywith the trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> of the nature andefficiency of its in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Learning frominstituti<strong>on</strong>-building experiences of industrialisedcountries and those in transiti<strong>on</strong> as well from otherdeveloping countries, can be valuable. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reare some good-practice examples from aroundthe world that illustrate how the c<strong>on</strong>straintsof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses have been successfullyaddressed through successful instituti<strong>on</strong>al andpolicy changes. At the same time, nati<strong>on</strong>al andlocal level instituti<strong>on</strong>al changes can be initiatedimplicitly with the introducti<strong>on</strong> of new ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivities that may well provide direct and measurablebenefits.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal EntrepreneurStreet vendors, rural milk hawkers, millers andginners, small food cart pushers, shoe shiners,the itinerant fix-it technician, the roadside hairdresserand food caterer — these are the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malentrepreneurs who are vibrant visible ec<strong>on</strong>omicplayers in the poorer countries of the world. Asan observer suggests, they are ‘the true entrepreneurs— more flexible, efficient and resilient thanthe over-regulated and overprotected dinosaursof the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector....’ 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se entrepreneurs arecalled in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal because they operate to some extentoutside the realm of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal regulati<strong>on</strong>and protecti<strong>on</strong>, and without easy or full access tothe advantages of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal financial and businesssupport systems.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are some 500 milli<strong>on</strong> working poor earningless than <strong>on</strong>e dollar per day (ILO 2004). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>197


vast majority earn their living in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, occupying land they do not own, workingin small, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses, and relying <strong>on</strong>family or friends <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal m<strong>on</strong>eylenders <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>loans. Often, they have limited access to broaderec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities and are especially vulnerableto the uncertainties, the corrupti<strong>on</strong> and eventhe violence prevalent outside the rule of law.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y have little or no access to settling disputesusing the legal machinery. Without legal rights orprotecti<strong>on</strong>s, they are in a c<strong>on</strong>tinual state of legaland political vulnerability. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,limits the opportunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic and socialdevelopment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals, families, businesses,communities, and even entire nati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO defines the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy as accommodating‘all ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities that are —inlaw or practice- not covered or insufficiently coveredby <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal arrangements.’ 3 It includes wageworkers and own-account workers and c<strong>on</strong>tributingfamily members. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs arethe working poor who run very small enterprises.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se include micro-entrepreneurs who hireworkers and two kinds of own-account operators,namely, heads-of-family businesses and singlepers<strong>on</strong>operators.Around the developing world, women tend tobe c<strong>on</strong>centrated in the low-end <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of ownaccountwork, and they are under-representedam<strong>on</strong>g micro-entrepreneurs. On average, earningsin in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises are low while costs andrisks are high, particularly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> own-account operators,but especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women operators.<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment and <strong>Legal</strong>Identity<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor, such that theirentrepreneurship is linked to greater ec<strong>on</strong>omicopportunity, means not <strong>on</strong>ly re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in legal codesbut also policies to correct asymmetries in accessto in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, educati<strong>on</strong> and training, and accessto financial, technical and business services.Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, the vast assortments of legal andregulatory rules and administrative systems, inwhich businesses are embedded, have to beexamined. A fundamental premise to all changeis that the legal identity of individuals as citizensand as entrepreneurs or workers must be clearlyestablished. For example, identity verificati<strong>on</strong>is essential to commercial dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>procedures and to local governance c<strong>on</strong>cerns.Similarly, property rights have ‘to be given toactual people, who themselves — in order to advanceand defend their access to and possessi<strong>on</strong>of such rights — first must be able to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallyverify their pers<strong>on</strong>al status and identity. A crucialpre-requisite, then, to enhancing the quality ofproperty rights is ensuring that residents/citizenshave recognised documents (such as birth, death,marriage and divorce certificates) verifying suchbasic in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> as their name, age, sex andmarital status.’ 4Based <strong>on</strong> evidence, we argue that there is need<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an effective and enabling envir<strong>on</strong>ment, regulatoryregime, commercial law and good ec<strong>on</strong>omicgovernance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> allowing business to operate withequitable ec<strong>on</strong>omic rights and guaranteeinggreater accountability in the government’s abilityto issue laws and the capacity to implement anden<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce them. This process should empower thepoor to use law and legal tools to prevail overpoverty, while persuading the government toequitably en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce its policies and regulati<strong>on</strong>s andrein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce the role of the civil society in implementinggreater accountability of all actors andat all levels. Sound ec<strong>on</strong>omic governance is builtup<strong>on</strong> principles of equity and equality of opportunities.Public policies and acti<strong>on</strong> there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e mustsupport access to and distributi<strong>on</strong> of assets, ec<strong>on</strong>omicopportunities, and political voice participa-198


ti<strong>on</strong> in decisi<strong>on</strong> making that promote sustainableenterprises. In order to effectively address thechallenge to ‘level the playing field,’ governancestructures have to emphasise greater investmentin the human resources of the poor, guarantees<strong>on</strong> business rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all and fairness in markets.Countries with pervasive inequalities in wealth,resources, weak instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and power typicallyexperience narrow financial sectors that meetthe needs of the privileged and the influential.Am<strong>on</strong>g the many market failures in developingcountries, notable are those in the financial marketsincluding those <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> credit, insurance, land,and human capital. With the c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> ofmarket power in a limited number of large banks,lending tends to get biased in the favour of enterprisesthat are low risk and may exclude thosewith the highest expected risk-adjusted returns.Access to finance is essential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> businesses;however businesses in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy lackaccess to financial markets and the capacity tocompete in product markets.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher the levels of inequities, the greaterwould be the propensity of the instituti<strong>on</strong>sand social arrangements to favour the interestsof the influential and the privileged. Inequitableinstituti<strong>on</strong>s generate ec<strong>on</strong>omic costs, which areavoidable. It is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e important to make surethat business rights do not provide exclusivebenefits and are not en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced selectively so that,both middle and poorer groups end up with unexploitedcapacity.An Integrated Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Approach<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment measures have to take placewithin a policy and regulatory approach whichrecognises that the two parts of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy —<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal — do not exist independentlyof each other. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a c<strong>on</strong>stant exchange ofideas, people, skills, goods and services betweenthe two parts. At the base of the private sectorare milli<strong>on</strong>s of small, micro, and mini entrepreneurs,who provide the bulk of the raw material<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector producti<strong>on</strong>, engage intermittentlyas labour in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises, anduse products made in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector. Thosewho have been employees in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sectorand have acquired new techniques, capabilitiesand business c<strong>on</strong>tacts, often move into the moreflexible in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector and set up their own businesses.If relati<strong>on</strong>ships between different levelsof ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity are to be anticipated, madestrategic and optimized, policy and instituti<strong>on</strong>alchange <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sustained business linkages and skillsdevelopment has to take place. Those who workin the micro-enterprises, and own-account workerswithin supply chains that lead into the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsector, have to be accorded legal protecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>a par with enterprises and workers in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsector.Successful design and support of appropriate policiesand instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an integrated ec<strong>on</strong>omymust begin with analysis of innovati<strong>on</strong>s emergingat the interface between the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal.Small producers and micro-entrepreneurs aredaily developing strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> dealing with thedemands of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s, while the latterhave also developed ways of managing their inevitableencounter with those who are the majorityin the poorer countries of the world. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se copingstrategies hold clues as to what developmentinterventi<strong>on</strong>s can and should build up<strong>on</strong>, withinthe c<strong>on</strong>text of particular cultures, ec<strong>on</strong>omies andindustries. C<strong>on</strong>textual specificity and less<strong>on</strong>sfrom <strong>on</strong>-the-ground experience, are importantprinciples <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy and instituti<strong>on</strong>al innovati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an integrated and inclusive ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Analysis of current practice could provide guidance<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the move from a bifurcated to an integrated,cohesive approach to entrepreneurship199


and ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity. First, in order to encouragegreater engagement between established<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses and the smaller enterprises,transacti<strong>on</strong> costs and risks of such engagementhave to be reduced. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the public sectorhas to develop and implement participatoryprocesses so that support is relevant to those <strong>on</strong>the fringes of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal activity. Third, change hasto be negotiated through iterative dialogue andpartnerships spanning across central and localgovernments, the private sector, domestic capitalmarkets, producer groups and their social andec<strong>on</strong>omic organisati<strong>on</strong>s. Fourth, the functi<strong>on</strong> inmicro and small scale entrepreneurial activity of‘immediate and direct reciprocities’ 5 has to berecognised; in many low-income communities,ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities and arrangements are embeddedin social relati<strong>on</strong>ships. How social relati<strong>on</strong>sand values, not just market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces, affect themodus operandi of milli<strong>on</strong>s of entrepreneurs hasto be brought into ec<strong>on</strong>omic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s.How social and cultural norms c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>the modes of producti<strong>on</strong> and overall situati<strong>on</strong> ofwomen entrepreneurs and indigenous peoples isparticularly pertinent to this c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m AgendaOur working group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chapter 4 of this reportrecommends the following as key messages in thelegal empowerment of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses:1. Policy Stance• <strong>Legal</strong>ly empowering small in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesrun by poor individuals or households shouldbe seen as a central pillar of a just societyand a central strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> reducing poverty andinequality.• Most policies and the global ec<strong>on</strong>omy currentlyaccord privilege to large firms/enterprises oversmall firms/enterprises.• In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality is here to stay and is an essentialfeature of the global ec<strong>on</strong>omy.• Poverty and exclusi<strong>on</strong> go hand in hand. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>poor have no choice but to accept insecurityand instability as a way of life. Our re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>magenda reflects the realities of poverty andexclusi<strong>on</strong> experienced by poor people, andthere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e focuses <strong>on</strong> removing the barriers thathold the poor back, and building a frameworkof laws and instituti<strong>on</strong>s to provide genuineprotecti<strong>on</strong> and opportunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all. This will requirewholesale systemic changes to all facetsof the legal framework, including: the politicalprocess, ec<strong>on</strong>omic policy, law making, publicadministrati<strong>on</strong>, and law en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement.• While nati<strong>on</strong>al governments and the internati<strong>on</strong>alcommunity should seek to create asmany <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal jobs as possible and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malise asmany in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises and jobs as possible,in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality is not going to disappear. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> realchallenge will be to reduce the ‘decent workdeficits’ of those who work in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally, especiallythe working poor.• Poor people’s enterprise does play a vital role inthe ec<strong>on</strong>omies of many countries, and the poorthere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e have a right to earn a living free fromharassment, extorti<strong>on</strong>, beating, wr<strong>on</strong>gful evicti<strong>on</strong>,expropriati<strong>on</strong> and exploitati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y mustbe offered equal opportunity to access local,nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>al markets.• Commercial rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs/operators should be seen as an essential partof a package of rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the working poorin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. This would includeproperty rights, labour rights, the right to socialprotecti<strong>on</strong>, and the right to organise and to berepresented in policymaking and rule-settinginstituti<strong>on</strong>s and processes.• Other than social protecti<strong>on</strong> (property, health,life, disability, old age) that is relevant <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> wage200


workers as well as the self-employed in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, commercial rights are relevantto the half of the working poor in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy who are self-employed.• Of the half of the working poor who are self-employed,the larger and more vulnerable groupare own-account operators, including bothsingle pers<strong>on</strong> operators and those who work infamily businesses or <strong>on</strong> family farms.• Productivity and protecti<strong>on</strong> can and should bepromoted together.• Ec<strong>on</strong>omic policies should address issues ofredistributi<strong>on</strong>.• <strong>Legal</strong> empowerment will stimulate growthwhich is <strong>on</strong> its turn a pre-c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> to reducepoverty.2. Policy Positi<strong>on</strong>s• On basic commercial rights: right to work,including right to vend; right to a work space(including public land and private residences)and to related basic infrastructure (shelter,electricity, water, sanitati<strong>on</strong>).• On intermediary commercial rights: right togovernment incentives and support (includingprocurement, tax holidays, export licensing,export promoti<strong>on</strong>), and right to public infrastructure(transport and communicati<strong>on</strong>).• On advanced commercial rights: entity shieldingrules, limited liability and capital lock-inrights, mechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> perpetual successi<strong>on</strong>of the firm and transferring its value, mechanismsto allow the use of standardised accounting,mechanisms to establish firm, managerand employee liability rights, protect minorityshareholders and default rules.3. Policy Process• Seeks to reduce the ‘decent work deficits’ ofthose who run in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses.• Includes representative voices of the workingpoor in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.• Recognises and addresses bias in existing commercialpolicies, regulati<strong>on</strong>s, laws, and proceduresthat favour larger firms/enterprises.• Seeks to extend government incentives andprocurements to the smallest in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises.• Seeks to build backward and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward linkages<strong>on</strong> fair terms between larger and smaller firms.• Promotes social protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators(property, health, life, disability insurance),and does retraining, life-l<strong>on</strong>g learning and othersupport to mobility.4. Practical StrategiesGood practice examples from around the worldcould help in devising local needs-based modelsto address local issues and c<strong>on</strong>straints.5. Policy DebatesDebates <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses.Formalisati<strong>on</strong> could take <strong>on</strong> different <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms,including:• Expanding <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment opportunities.• Creating incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malise, such as:• Simplified registrati<strong>on</strong> procedures and progressiveregistrati<strong>on</strong> fees.• Supportive investment climate.• Fair commercial transacti<strong>on</strong>s between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal firms.• Appropriate legal and regulatory frameworks,including en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable commercial c<strong>on</strong>tracts,property rights and use of public space.• Tax-funded incentives, including: govern-201


ment procurement, tax rebates, and taxfundedsubsidies and incentive packages.• Provisi<strong>on</strong> of financial, business and marketingservices.• Creating mechanisms and financial arrangementsto provide social protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malproducers.• Promoting participatory policy processes andinclusive rule-setting instituti<strong>on</strong>s that involverepresentatives of associati<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malentrepreneurs.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> broad effect of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in attaining legal empowermentwill not <strong>on</strong>ly improve the well-beingand livelihoods of individual entrepreneurs; it willalso result in enhanced social protecti<strong>on</strong>, as wellas increased productivity and asset base of poorpeople and of the nati<strong>on</strong> as a whole.I. Introducti<strong>on</strong> andFrameworkSince the phrase ‘in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector’ was coinedin the early 1970s 6 to describe the range ofsubsistence activities of the urban poor, there hasbeen c<strong>on</strong>siderable debate about its definiti<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector is not homogenous; it encompassesdifferent types of ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities,different labour relati<strong>on</strong>s that range from the selfemployed,paid and unpaid, to disguised wageworkers and ec<strong>on</strong>omies with different ec<strong>on</strong>omicpotential that includes survivalist ec<strong>on</strong>omies andsuccessful micro and small enterprises. In effect,the term ‘in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy’ is more appropriateas it comprises the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector while notexcluding possible linkages of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operatorswith the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector. 7Generally speaking, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyencompasses the expanding an increasinglydiverse groups of workers and businesses inboth rural and urban areas, operating in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally— i.e., they are not recognised or protectedunder the legal and regulatory frameworks. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>nati<strong>on</strong>al and local ec<strong>on</strong>omies c<strong>on</strong>tinue to be ac<strong>on</strong>tinuum that ranges from in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy has been growing at arapid rate throughout the world, including in theindustrialised countries. In recent years, much ofthe employment potential within the developingcountries has been found in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omiesand, hence, in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises.In these countries, a much higher proporti<strong>on</strong> ofthose working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy are poor,with the share of women relative to men beingmuch higher.202Accordingly, the legal empowerment agenda<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business rights emphasises re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, creatingmechanisms and financial arrangements toprovide social protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal producers.


Good initiatives have been undertaken by ILO,the World Bank, USAID, am<strong>on</strong>g other organisati<strong>on</strong>s,to provide the poor and the disadvantagedwith the legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment andthe rule of law in order that they might betterdevelop their capacity to use their own talents,energy and initiative <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> accessing livelihoodresources, and assets to generate efficient andproductive enterprises. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ultimate goal is toguarantee sustainable livelihoods <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all — al<strong>on</strong>gthe c<strong>on</strong>tinuum from the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> approach: reorienting gender-baseddevelopment strategies to eradicate poverty. Thisrequires 1) a better understanding of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses and enterprises within the c<strong>on</strong>text ofthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal c<strong>on</strong>tinuum, and 2) an integrativestrategy to design a system of businessrights that provides soluti<strong>on</strong>s to the lack of socialprotecti<strong>on</strong>, lack of representati<strong>on</strong> and voice,and leads to more efficient ec<strong>on</strong>omic functi<strong>on</strong>ing,greater trust and reducti<strong>on</strong> in c<strong>on</strong>flict, andimproved instituti<strong>on</strong>s with dynamic benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>equitable investment and growth.This chapter <strong>on</strong> Business Rights presentsevidence to dem<strong>on</strong>strate that the inequality ofbusiness opportunities available to the poor isunec<strong>on</strong>omical and detrimental to sustainabledevelopment and poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. It will alsoprovide policy and rule of law implicati<strong>on</strong>s emergingfrom removal of bureaucratic and administrativeinefficiencies in the life cycle of businessesand the study of market failures, particularly atthe local levels, while building up<strong>on</strong> the broadc<strong>on</strong>cept of levelling the playing field — politicallyand ec<strong>on</strong>omically — in the domestic and globalarenas.Why Business Rights? And why now?We live in world of increasing inequities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>richest two percent of adults own more than 50percent of global assets. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poorest half of thepopulati<strong>on</strong> holds <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e percent of wealth. 8Unprecedented affluence co-exists with ast<strong>on</strong>ishingdeprivati<strong>on</strong>, persistence of poverty and unmetbasic needs, violati<strong>on</strong> of fundamental politicalfreedoms, and neglect or even absence of lawfulprivileges that uphold basic civil liberties <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> asignificant proporti<strong>on</strong> of the populati<strong>on</strong>. Nearly40 percent of the world’s 6.5 billi<strong>on</strong> peoplelive in poverty of which, a sixth live in extremepoverty. 9 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number of people living in extremepoverty in Africa has nearly doubled from 164milli<strong>on</strong> in 1981 to 316 milli<strong>on</strong> in 2001. Even <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the rest of the world, extreme poverty today hasincreased by nearly three percent from 1981. 10While the deprivati<strong>on</strong>s indicated above are morecomm<strong>on</strong> in the less wealthy countries, they existin, <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m or another, in rich countries too. 11<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>, being central to our lives, is a basic requirementto enriching human well-being and thequality of life in general. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowers peopleto enhance their ability to attain and sustainlivelihoods, while it is largely left to business tocreate savings, investment and innovati<strong>on</strong> thatc<strong>on</strong>tribute to livelihoods and to employmentgenerati<strong>on</strong>. 12 Persistent poverty may be blamed<strong>on</strong> both public policy failure and market failure.Interestingly, the two are related in that prevalentpolicies and resulting systems of governancestructure and legal rights have largely served tocharacterise the functi<strong>on</strong> of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy, marketsand businesses, and to define what they cando and what they are allowed to do. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,an integral c<strong>on</strong>stituent of poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> musthave to do with empowering the working poor toaccess opportunities that could be created byreducing ec<strong>on</strong>omic, legal and social inequalities.Businesses, generally speaking, c<strong>on</strong>stitute theprivate sector; they are usually led private individuals,communities and corporati<strong>on</strong>s. In many203


developing countries, however, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprisesovershadow the private sector and theirnumber is increasing. Creati<strong>on</strong> of good qualityjobs is determined to a large extent by enterprisecreati<strong>on</strong>, innovati<strong>on</strong> and expansi<strong>on</strong>. Where thepotential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> entrepreneurship, creativity, dynamicand productive job creati<strong>on</strong> is stifled, eitherthrough <strong>on</strong>erous legal procedures and instituti<strong>on</strong>sor through inequities represented by vested interestsand inadequate en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement, entrepreneurswill gravitate towards the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal firms and enterprises account <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> morethan 50 percent of all ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities andsome estimates c<strong>on</strong>clude that over 30 percent ofthe developing world’s GDP and 70 percent of itworkers are outside the official ec<strong>on</strong>omy. 13 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>size of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is inversely relatedto ec<strong>on</strong>omic development and, while, at thesame time, there is a significant corresp<strong>on</strong>dencebetween working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy andbeing poor. However, a large number of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses in an ec<strong>on</strong>omy are not per se a sign ofits underdevelopment; they are, rather, a reflecti<strong>on</strong>of the fact that these enterprises are c<strong>on</strong>finedto subsistence and insufficiently productiveactivities.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy in Africa is estimated tohave been 42 percent of GDP in 2000. WhileZimbabwe, Tanzania and Nigeria were at the highend with the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector representing 59.4percent, 58.3 percent and 57.9 percent of respectiveGDP, Botswana and Camero<strong>on</strong> were at thelower end, with 33.4 percent and 32.8 percentrespectively. At the turn of the century, 93 percentof the jobs created in Sub-Saharan Africa werein the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, 14 with almost 80 percentof n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural employment and over 60percent of urban employment. 15 In Latin America,the average size of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy was 41percent of GDP with Bolivia as the largest in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy at 67.1 percent, and Chile as thesmallest at 19.8 percent. In Asia, the range variedfrom Thailand at 52.6 percent, to Singapore with13.1 percent. In transiti<strong>on</strong> countries, by far thelargest in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy was in Georgia with 67.3percent, and at the lower end were the Czech Republicwith 19.1 percent and the Slovak Republicwith 18.9 percent.In the recent years, the li<strong>on</strong>’s share of newemployment in developing countries has beenin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Activities in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy provide certain benefits to a marginalfew. Also, while some activities in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy provide viable livelihoods with reas<strong>on</strong>ableincomes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> some, most in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers earninsecure incomes under c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that are not <strong>on</strong>par with decent work standards. 16 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y do not, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, receive medical or other benefits. 17 In effect,the decent work deficits are most pr<strong>on</strong>ouncedin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy where most workers havelittle or no social protecti<strong>on</strong> and receive little orno social security. Also, poor respect and lack offreedom of associati<strong>on</strong> make it difficult <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theseworkers and their employers to organise. 18 In additi<strong>on</strong>,working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyare often unsafe, uncertain, and poor in terms ofremunerati<strong>on</strong>. Other c<strong>on</strong>cerns are poor occupati<strong>on</strong>alhealth and safety arrangements, and realfears <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sexual harassment and violence againstwomen. Furthermore, wages are suppressed belowadequate levels and fail to reward productivity orl<strong>on</strong>g service. 19 Finally, the lack of social protecti<strong>on</strong>measures, such as rights and representati<strong>on</strong>,leave many in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce trapped inpoverty. 20 Nearly all in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers are am<strong>on</strong>gthe poorest citizens of their respective countries,and they lack educati<strong>on</strong>, m<strong>on</strong>ey and the ability to204


obtain <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal, permanent work. 21 It is importantto add that a larger proporti<strong>on</strong> of women relativeto men work in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and suffersfrom poverty.<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment and BusinessRights<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy includes a growing andincreasingly diverse group of workers and ruraland urban enterprises operating in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally. Whilethe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy comprises both producti<strong>on</strong>units of various kinds and elements of employmentstatus, this paper will focus mainly <strong>on</strong> businessrights relating to small entrepreneurs andthe self-employed. Business rights are integralcomp<strong>on</strong>ents of the strength of an ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Whilemilli<strong>on</strong>s in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy may be wagelabourers, c<strong>on</strong>sisting of paid, unpaid and disguisedwage recipients in ‘value chains’, engagedin survival-type activities, there are nevertheless asignificant proporti<strong>on</strong> of poor people who are selfemployedin micro-enterprises, operating theirown business ventures, or c<strong>on</strong>tributing familyworkers, or employees.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> problems and needs under each of thesecategories may be different, but they neverthelessfall into the ‘in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal’ category because theylack recogniti<strong>on</strong> or protecti<strong>on</strong> under the legal,instituti<strong>on</strong>al and regulatory, judicial and disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong> frameworks. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also lack access tothe advantages of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal financial and businesssupport systems. In additi<strong>on</strong>, they are excludedfrom, or have limited access to, public infrastructureand other benefits of the public goods aswell as to markets and they are there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e unableto be competitive or efficient in managing theiractivities. This, in turn increases their vulnerabilityto natural, social and political shocks andstresses and places doubt <strong>on</strong> the sustainability oftheir livelihoods.It is argued that prevalence and increase in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusiness is a c<strong>on</strong>sequence of inequitablepolicies and discriminatory en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement that failto give support to those businesses and entrepreneurialopportunities in which tangible benefitsmight accrue to the poor. Accordingly, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> mostsmall entrepreneurs and self-employed people,working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is a survivalstrategy rather than an opti<strong>on</strong>.Balancing Human Rightsand Market-Based Approach<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment aims to address relativedeprivati<strong>on</strong> in all <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, including social,political and ec<strong>on</strong>omic dimensi<strong>on</strong>s in the pursuitof a life of choice, freedom, respect and dignity.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> issue of equity, in having rights and beingable to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce them, is critical, as it relatesto the disparities in capabilities which reflects<strong>on</strong> access to wealth and resources as well as toownership of assets. While the rich and privilegedcan protect themselves and their rights by legalmeans as well as by influence and c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s,the poor must rely <strong>on</strong> legally en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable rights.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> recogniti<strong>on</strong> of human rights is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e necessary.Equally necessary are the legal means andcapacities to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce those rights through accessibleand effective instituti<strong>on</strong>s and processes thatare transparent, participatory and accountable.At the same time, instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms designedto eradicate poverty need to be put into place toensure that state and public policies work, thatregulati<strong>on</strong> to create greater equity is in place, andthat the system will work to help the poor and thedisadvantaged to create wealth — even throughentrepreneurship.Public investments are crucial <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> developing thatkind of ‘private based ec<strong>on</strong>omy’ that could allowthe private sector to create employment and sustainl<strong>on</strong>g- term ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. In the absence205


of the provisi<strong>on</strong> of adequate infrastructure, healthservices and educati<strong>on</strong>, market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces al<strong>on</strong>e canaccomplish little. Existence of markets is a prerequisite<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> survival and sustainability of businessesand entrepreneurs. While the freedom toenter a market 22 is a vital c<strong>on</strong>stituent of development,the level of access and representati<strong>on</strong> inthose markets determines the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malcharacter of an enterprise and what it can accomplish.Again, the markets cannot functi<strong>on</strong>in the absence of effective and equitable publicpolicy, rule of law, regulati<strong>on</strong>, social support andpolitical freedoms. In principle, the markets, inadditi<strong>on</strong> to creating ec<strong>on</strong>omic efficiency, can alsoencourage greater ec<strong>on</strong>omic equity. This would,however, depend <strong>on</strong> the structure of markets,their governance and associated legal rights, andthe nature and extent of their inclusiveness asreflected through active business enterprises.Private instituti<strong>on</strong>s are willing to develop innovativepartnership models to provide greater accessto goods and services by the poor. But they requireassistance through appropriate policies andstrengthened capacities to remove barriers to themarket creati<strong>on</strong> and provide greater market accessto the entrepreneurs in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omies.At the same time, governments shouldnot hesitate to step in, possibly in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ofpublic-private partnerships, that would encourageprivate instituti<strong>on</strong>s to meet the demands ofthe poor and enhance market access in rural andunderserved areas 23 .Ec<strong>on</strong>omic success requires getting the balanceright between the government and the market,in terms of who should provide the goods andservices and how they should be provided. Anysuccessful development strategy demands theexistence of equitable access to markets by alland requires involvement of government, marketsand the private sector, and the civil society.Voice, Representati<strong>on</strong> and EffectiveEc<strong>on</strong>omic GovernanceIt is essential to build up<strong>on</strong> and refine the aboveissues in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the work of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor (CLEP)and re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the development agenda by broadeningthe discussi<strong>on</strong> of business rights and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy in a comprehensive manner thatgoes bey<strong>on</strong>d <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> per se. It will emphasisethat the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor tocreate and operate their enterprises and generatesustainable livelihoods sustainably requires themto have a voice in all aspects of policymaking,implementati<strong>on</strong> and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement, and to havethe ability to work with governments and otherstakeholders to create new rights, capacities, andopportunities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> adverse effects of unequal opportunitiesof representati<strong>on</strong> and political voice andpower <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poorer people <strong>on</strong> human developmentare particularly harmful because ec<strong>on</strong>omic,political, and social inequalities tend to reproducethemselves over time and across generati<strong>on</strong>s,setting into moti<strong>on</strong> a poverty trap that doesnot allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improvements in the quality of theirlives.Business rights should result in the creati<strong>on</strong> ofan efficient and inclusive private sector with asound domestic macro envir<strong>on</strong>ment, having tradepolicies, instituti<strong>on</strong>al foundati<strong>on</strong>s and adequatecapacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> maximising benefits from the macroglobal envir<strong>on</strong>ment and promoting distributi<strong>on</strong>alequity.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is evidence, we believe, to argue the case<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an effective and enabling envir<strong>on</strong>ment, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> aregulatory regime and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> commercial law, as wellas good ec<strong>on</strong>omic governance that would allowbusiness to operate with equitable ec<strong>on</strong>omicrights and guarantee greater accountability in206


the government’s ability to issue, implement anden<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce laws. This would empower the poor to uselaw and legal tools to prevail over poverty, whilepersuading the government to equitably en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceits policies and regulati<strong>on</strong>s and rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce the roleof the civil society in implementing greater accountabilityof all actors and at all levels. Soundec<strong>on</strong>omic governance is built up<strong>on</strong> principlesof equity and equality of opportunities. Publicpolicies and acti<strong>on</strong>, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, must supportaccess to and distributi<strong>on</strong> of assets, ec<strong>on</strong>omicopportunities, and political voice participati<strong>on</strong> indecisi<strong>on</strong>-making that works to promote sustainableenterprises. In order to effectively addressthe challenge of ‘levelling the playing field’,governance structures have to emphasise greaterinvestment in the human resources of the poor,guarantees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all, and fairnessin markets.Greater Access to Markets, Goods andServices, and InfrastructureIt is vital to have functi<strong>on</strong>al legal principles andmechanisms that will enable entrepreneurs andbusinesses in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy to havegreater access to goods and services and marketsso they can build productive and efficient businessenterprises. At the minimum, this requiresthe existence of equitable opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepoor to create, run and manage a business. Inturn, it translates into strengthened capabilitiesof the poor to access and effectively useresources, infrastructure, and c<strong>on</strong>stituent comp<strong>on</strong>ents24 of a business and factors of producti<strong>on</strong>.With such assurances, they could efficientlytrans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m their labour into a successful business.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y could manage it to obtain certain profit, anduse the secure asset base to expand that businesssuccessfully. For a business to be sustainable,the entrepreneur should have the abilityto manage a high level of pers<strong>on</strong>al, professi<strong>on</strong>aland financial risk, as well as the risk of physical,envir<strong>on</strong>mental and socially adverse impacts,in additi<strong>on</strong> to the capacity to recover from thoseshocks.In the presence of missing or imperfect markets,the distributi<strong>on</strong> of wealth and power affects theallocati<strong>on</strong> of investment opportunities. Achievingec<strong>on</strong>omic efficiency would necessitate the combinati<strong>on</strong>of acti<strong>on</strong>s relating to correcti<strong>on</strong> of the marketfailure as well as measures to provide greateraccess to services, assets, and political influenceby the disenfranchised suffering from adverseimpacts of inequitable development strategies.Inclusive Financial ServicesCountries with pervasive inequalities in wealth,resources, weak instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and power typicallyexperience narrow financial sectors that meet theneeds of the privileged and the influential. Am<strong>on</strong>gthe many market failures in developing countries,the most notable are those in the financialmarkets, including those in the areas of credit,insurance, land, and human capital. With thec<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> of market power in a limited numberof large banks, lending tends to get biased in thefavour of enterprises that are low risk. This mayexclude those with the highest expected risk-adjustedreturns. Access to finance is essential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>businesses; however businesses in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy lack access to financial markets and thecapacity to compete in product markets.Over 4 billi<strong>on</strong> people globally are currently irrelevantto the banking system. Normally, accessto commercial banks by the low income andrural populati<strong>on</strong>s is limited in terms of physicaldistance to the closest branch of the bank andalso because of thresholds in account fees orminimum required balances. While large companiesare well served by existing banking system,low income and rural individuals, micro-entre-207


preneurs and small sector enterprises are particularlyunder-serviced by the financial industry.For instance, nearly 741 milli<strong>on</strong> Indians in ruralareas are poorly served, despite a huge demand<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial services, including an estimated annualcredit demand exceeding US$10 billi<strong>on</strong>. 25Similarly, those in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy are notcovered by safety and health regulati<strong>on</strong>s and arenot, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, eligible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> social security benefits,pensi<strong>on</strong>s or other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of social protecti<strong>on</strong>.Enhanced access to basic financial services— savings, credit, insurance, pensi<strong>on</strong>s andtools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> risk management — is a critical input <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>emerging and potential entrepreneurs to leverageec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities and improve their qualityof life. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ability and willingness of private financialinstituti<strong>on</strong>s to provide access to inclusivefinancial services would depend <strong>on</strong> appropriatepolicies, existence of relevant human and instituti<strong>on</strong>alcapacities that would remove barriersto the market creati<strong>on</strong>, as well as incentives topartner with the private sector to provide broadermarket access to the entrepreneurs who requiregreater facilitati<strong>on</strong> and empowerment. At thesame time, the government should not hesitate tostep in through policies, regulati<strong>on</strong>s and incentivesto encourage private financial instituti<strong>on</strong>sto garner savings, l<strong>on</strong>g term credit and marketbasedsocial protecti<strong>on</strong> instruments in rural andunderserved areas. 26 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> regulatory structures,there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, have to ensure broader access to financialservices, particularly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor, as well asa deepening of the financial sector and establishmentof greater accountability.Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Changes<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher the levels of inequities, the greaterwould be the propensity of the instituti<strong>on</strong>s andsocial arrangements to favour the interests ofthe influential and the privileged. Inequitableinstituti<strong>on</strong>s generate ec<strong>on</strong>omic costs, which areavoidable. It is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e important to make surethat the business rights do not provide exclusivebenefits and are not en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced selectively, whichwould leave both middle and poorer groups withunexploited capacity.As the realms of instituti<strong>on</strong>al and ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment are reciprocally related, knowledgeof nati<strong>on</strong>al and local c<strong>on</strong>texts is critical. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,internati<strong>on</strong>al comparis<strong>on</strong>s of ‘ease of doingbusiness’ need to take into account the realityof the nature, quality and experience of differentcountries. Although the private sector in developingcountries is largely comprised of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses, the character and attributes of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector will most certainly vary from <strong>on</strong>ecountry to the next. It would there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e appear thatthe effectiveness of recommendati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>venienceof doing business should be measuredby the extent to which the proposed changesare mainstreamed and translated into improvedper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance of the instituti<strong>on</strong>s and their operatingenvir<strong>on</strong>ment. Without such measure, theexpected increase in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign investment would beillusory.Because the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesare predominantly local, the criteria determiningease of doing business must incorporatethe needs of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses. Subsequentrecommendati<strong>on</strong>s should there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e encompassand be judged by the ability of the macro-levelchanges to the business climate to impact locallevelinstituti<strong>on</strong>s and, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, businesses in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Improvement in the quality of instituti<strong>on</strong>s in anec<strong>on</strong>omy has to proceed simultaneously with thetrans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> of its in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Valuableless<strong>on</strong>s can be learned from the instituti<strong>on</strong>-buildingexperience of the industrialised countries208


and those in transiti<strong>on</strong>, as well as from otherdeveloping countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are good-practiceexamples from around the world that illustratehow c<strong>on</strong>straints of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses have beensuccessfully addressed through instituti<strong>on</strong>al andpolicy change. At the same time, nati<strong>on</strong>al andlocal level instituti<strong>on</strong>al changes can be initiatedimplicitly by launching new ec<strong>on</strong>omic activitiesthat provide direct and measurable benefitsto those who will be influenced by instituti<strong>on</strong>alchange. As the process c<strong>on</strong>tinues, the ability ofa populati<strong>on</strong>, impacted by instituti<strong>on</strong>al change,to realise tangible benefits will provide proof oftheir ownership. Over time, the ec<strong>on</strong>omic activitybecomes an agent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> and a catalyst of demand<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> appropriate instituti<strong>on</strong>s. 27 For instance, ec<strong>on</strong>omicempowerment based <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic activityis a step towards gender equality, 28 even if theyare not syn<strong>on</strong>ymous. Linking creative ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivities with business rights in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy has an added advantage in that it allowslearning-by-doing in implementing instituti<strong>on</strong>alre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. It also allows <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> synergistic linkages betweenre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms from above (including those initiatedby governments or promoted by internati<strong>on</strong>alorganisati<strong>on</strong>s) with effective acti<strong>on</strong> from below(by civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s and organisati<strong>on</strong>sof the poor themselves).Pursuing the Agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Change<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> emphasis of the document is placed <strong>on</strong>creating larger opti<strong>on</strong>s and opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>entrepreneurs and businesses in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omies to operate proficiently and equippingthem with capabilities, enabling envir<strong>on</strong>mentand equitable governance systems to make correctchoices to maximise their welfare. 29<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment Framework does not look to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malising ec<strong>on</strong>omies as the desired outcome;instead, it urges the creati<strong>on</strong> of circumstances inwhich the ultimate benefits of the developmentinterventi<strong>on</strong>s will accrue in equitable manner tothe poor <strong>on</strong> a sustainable basis.An important focus of the paper <strong>on</strong> BusinessRights is the use of an evidence-based approach.It is anticipated that the analysis will establishempirical linkages to illustrate legal rights andempowerment of the poor by tackling the intricacyof the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and proposing amethodology and sequence of acti<strong>on</strong>s to addressthe underlying complex issues of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesand poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change’ proposes a comprehensivestrategy to address three inter-relatedcomp<strong>on</strong>ents that run the c<strong>on</strong>tinuum fromthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal end of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy;they include:• Creating more entrepreneurship and businessopportunities by ensuring that those in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy are legally recognised; theyshould have legal social protecti<strong>on</strong> and riskmanagement opti<strong>on</strong>s, equitable representati<strong>on</strong>and voice, as well as and assurances that thenew enterprises do not have an incentive to bein the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector simply because of lowercost.• Enabling those enterprises currently in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy to move upwards al<strong>on</strong>g thec<strong>on</strong>tinuum, through a c<strong>on</strong>text-specific mix oflegal policy frameworks that include incentivesand regulati<strong>on</strong>s, as well as assurances that theentrepreneurs have the capacity and flexibilityto do so.• Improving productivity, efficiencies and c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s,and increasing the returns <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the businessesin the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector.It is obvious that the interventi<strong>on</strong>s under thethree categories will have comm<strong>on</strong> characteristics.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> guiding principle would be to tackle theroot causes of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses rather than209


negative manifestati<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesand in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>. Also, the changes have tooccur at the local level, which basically definesthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Successful mobilisati<strong>on</strong> ofbusinesses at local level, whether by the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tsof government, private sector or NGO, is a greatpromoter of equitable ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Whilesuch interventi<strong>on</strong>s would be local in nature, theirimplementati<strong>on</strong> recognises the global (universal)c<strong>on</strong>text that influences all development activities.In the end, the success and sustainabilityof any re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m will depend <strong>on</strong> public recogniti<strong>on</strong>and ownership of evidence-based trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>within the cultural, social and political milieu. 30To Sum UpThis introducti<strong>on</strong> provided an overall framework<strong>on</strong> the legal empowerment agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> businessrights and sets the stage <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the secti<strong>on</strong>s thatfollow. We proposed that re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms can help thepoor and the disadvantaged with the legal andinstituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment and the rule of law.People would then be encouraged to developtheir capacities, energies and initiatives and toaccess livelihood resources, build assets andgenerate efficient and productive enterprises. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>next secti<strong>on</strong> will look at in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses andenterprises within the c<strong>on</strong>text of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malc<strong>on</strong>tinuum; it will examine the relati<strong>on</strong>shipbetween the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, poverty and productivity,and it will map the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omiesthat involve women and indigenous people.2. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy andIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal BusinessesIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal-Formal C<strong>on</strong>tinuumEven though any debate <strong>on</strong> ‘in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality’ centres<strong>on</strong> the dichotomy between <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal andin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal, the c<strong>on</strong>cept is a lesser representative ofdualism and embodies a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum when viewedfrom any of the perspectives of activities, instituti<strong>on</strong>sor c<strong>on</strong>tracts. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> definiti<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality,however, is ambiguous and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omydenotes a plurality of activities that are also c<strong>on</strong>textual.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> term ‘in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector’ is inadequatebecause it fails to represent the inherent heterogeneity,complexity and dynamism of this ec<strong>on</strong>omyand its c<strong>on</strong>stituent activities. Also, the genderbias in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is probably underestimatedand women are more likely to be in thosein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal activities that are under-counted, includingproducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> own c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and paiddomestic activities in private households. Based<strong>on</strong> the ILO’s classificati<strong>on</strong>, 31 the term ‘in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy’ has come to be widely used to includethe expanding and increasingly diverse group ofworkers and enterprises in both rural and urbanareas, operating without recogniti<strong>on</strong> under legaland protective frameworks, and characterised bya high degree of vulnerability.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is differentiated in termsof producti<strong>on</strong> units as well as employment status.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal may there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e refer to firm features oftypes of firms, or it may refer to employment. Itmay also be characterised as an activity or a typeof activity. On the <strong>on</strong>e hand, it includes own-accountworkers in survival type activities, rangingfrom street vendors, cobblers and shoe shiners,garbage collectors and rag pickers, to the selfemployedentrepreneurs. On the other hand, therange of wage earners — from aid domestic work-210


ers employed by households, to ‘disguised wageworkers’ employed by sweatshops in producti<strong>on</strong>chains — are also included as important c<strong>on</strong>stituentsof the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Not surprisingly, any discussi<strong>on</strong> of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy would include ‘small’ enterprises notregulated, as well as employment relati<strong>on</strong>shipsthat are not legally recognised and that leavemuch to be desired (in terms of providing socialprotecti<strong>on</strong> and reducti<strong>on</strong> of vulnerability). Wemay note here that issues relating to employability,productivity and flexibility of the labour<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce and to their upward movement al<strong>on</strong>g thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal c<strong>on</strong>tinuum are the subject ofChapter 3 of this report <strong>on</strong> Labour Rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>thrust of this discussi<strong>on</strong>, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, will maintainthe focus <strong>on</strong> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses and enterpriseswhich, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the purpose of analysis, include ownaccountoperators. We examine legal measuresthat include the presence of, and equitable accessto, effective judicial, political and ec<strong>on</strong>omic,market and n<strong>on</strong>-market instituti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se, wehave observed, make it easier <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> micro and smallenterprises to start up and grow in a manner thatallows them to adopt ‘high road’ strategies toenhance efficiency and productivity and providedecent jobs <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> its employees.Poverty and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omyIncreasing poverty spurs growth of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. In turn, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy promotesec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, serving to reduce poverty. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>problem here is that any reducti<strong>on</strong> in poverty isinefficient, and lacks legal recogniti<strong>on</strong>, regulati<strong>on</strong>and protecti<strong>on</strong>. Studies of countries that havesuccessfully delivered pro-poor growth suggestthat even though ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth is extremelyimportant, it is unable, by itself, to address theeventual disparity in poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. It is necessaryto address the nature of inequalities whileaccounting <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the resulting change, if any, ininequality from this kind of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. 32In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and data <strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyin developing countries is sketchy since very fewcountries undertake survey of employment andengagement in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy <strong>on</strong> a regularbasis. Even though nearly 75 percent of the poorpeople in developing countries live in rural areasand engage in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities relatedto agriculture, many countries exclude agriculturefrom their measurement of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.33An in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector survey carried out by ILOin 1995 found that 41 percent of the workerswere in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy because theycould not find any other work (including thosewho became involved following their retrenchment),30 percent because their family neededadditi<strong>on</strong>al income, 10 percent because of thefreedom to determine their hours or place ofwork, and 9 percent because of good incomeopportunities. 34 Although not all poor are inthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, almost all those who arein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal are poor. Urban areas of most developingcountries expose the c<strong>on</strong>temporaneous existenceof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers’ shacks with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers’more affluent homes. In the name of ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of propertyrights, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer are first to be destroyed by governmenteven though the services provided to the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements by them are perfectly legal.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal EnterprisesDespite the fact that the self-employed andemployers face many barriers to setting up andoperating in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises, they account <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>70 percent of the jobs in sub-Saharan Africa andabout 60 percent in the other developing regi<strong>on</strong>s.In India, nearly 93 percent of the work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce is inthe self-organised in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector, with nearly 10211


milli<strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>s and their dependents relying <strong>on</strong>street vending <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their livelihood. 35Studies alsoindicate that in the absence of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omies,a majority of private sector householdswould have fallen deeper into poverty. 36<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a prevalent assumpti<strong>on</strong> that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises exist by choice because of theowners’ preference to curtail labour costs andavoid payment of taxes. While this is true, it isnot the entire story. Many businesses in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy have limited output, employment orincome to even be at the level of taxable entities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> root causes of the manifestati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises encompass the legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>alhurdles that make it difficult to become or stay<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal. For instance, the regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>mentmay be excessively burdensome, overly punitiveand especially, in the cases of crises countries,n<strong>on</strong>-existent. In additi<strong>on</strong>, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesseshave little access to public infrastructure and depend<strong>on</strong> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and unfair instituti<strong>on</strong>al arrangements<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their essentials. Essentials could rangebroadly from credit, markets and n<strong>on</strong>-marketinstituti<strong>on</strong>s, training, developing skills and knowledge,to social protecti<strong>on</strong>, and even in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> demographic trends (including rural-urbanmigrati<strong>on</strong> and cross-border labour migrati<strong>on</strong>), andnati<strong>on</strong>al policies that c<strong>on</strong>strain or limit employmentgenerati<strong>on</strong> in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Lack of registrati<strong>on</strong> and regulati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses and enterprises prevents in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malworkers from enjoying the rights of the decentwork that may be accorded under their nati<strong>on</strong>allabour legislati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> use of the term ‘in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal’does not mean an absence of norms or rules <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>operati<strong>on</strong>s of the enterprises. Businesses in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy have their own instituti<strong>on</strong>s,mechanisms, rules, financial arrangements, andsystems <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> accessing technology and markets,but they lack a comm<strong>on</strong> framework and it is unclearif they observe the fundamental and humanrights of the labour. Also a number of criminalactivities — m<strong>on</strong>ey laundering, human and drugtrafficking, tax evasi<strong>on</strong>, etc. — are in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, as they operate <strong>on</strong> the fringes of thelaw. This area, however, is bey<strong>on</strong>d the scope ofour chapter.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises and ProductivityA large in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector can be an indicati<strong>on</strong> ofhigh regulatory costs <strong>on</strong> business, raising doubts<strong>on</strong> the value of the regulati<strong>on</strong>s themselves. Studies37 have found that the size of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsector, also termed ‘shadow ec<strong>on</strong>omy’, could beinversely related to Gross Development Product(See Figure 1). In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality restrains efficient useof resources and productivity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> inefficiency orsub-optimal productivity of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyis there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e linked in part, to the absence of legalprotecti<strong>on</strong>, inability to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce c<strong>on</strong>tracts and theneed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> security that comes from the dearth ofproperty rights and decent work attributes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>irability to organise <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> social protecti<strong>on</strong> is weak,with little or no voice to make their businessrecognised or protected. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> lack of voice andparticipati<strong>on</strong> in decisi<strong>on</strong>-making leads to n<strong>on</strong>existenceof ec<strong>on</strong>omic rights or opportunities toachieve their full ec<strong>on</strong>omic potential.An ec<strong>on</strong>omy with a large proporti<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses functi<strong>on</strong>s below its potential, with alower rate of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. 38 It also servesto point up systemic inequities in the abilityof entrepreneurs to access markets, resources,technology, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, public infrastructureand social services. However, the large number ofsmall firms in developing countries is not in itselfa sign of their underdevelopment, but, rather, areflecti<strong>on</strong> of their c<strong>on</strong>finement to insufficientlyproductive activities.It is important to design policies and mechanisms212


Figure 1 GDP Per Capita and the Size of the Shadow Ec<strong>on</strong>omyGDP per capita (c<strong>on</strong>stant 1995 US$50 00045 000•40 000•35 000Norway30 000••25 000Belgum• • • • •20 000•15 000• UK •••10 000• •5 000Est<strong>on</strong>ia Hungary• PeruGuatemala EgyptI I • • • ••• • • I••• • •• • •I •• • •• •I Tunisia • I I • • I• • I0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80Size of the shadow ec<strong>on</strong>omy (% of GDP) Source: Erneste & Schneider 1998Figure 2 Indigenous private sector development and regulati<strong>on</strong> in Africa and Central Europe:a 10-country studyGDP Per Capita growth rate against sum of policy and instituti<strong>on</strong>s to improve the enablingenvir<strong>on</strong>ment: 1995-1999GDP Growth rate 1995-19996%5%4%3%2%1%0%• Uganda• Poland• Latvia• HungaryMalawi•Ghana•• Tanzania4 I ZambiaSouth Africa• Kenya6 I •8 I 10 I 12 I 14 I 16 I 18 IPolicy and instituti<strong>on</strong>s Source: Bannock, G. et al. August 2002that enable the participati<strong>on</strong> and access to benefitsfrom growth by the poor people. This requiresa c<strong>on</strong>scious and sustained ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t by governmentsto create necessary c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> broad-basedgrowth in regi<strong>on</strong>s and sectors where the poor liveand work. 39 While it is not guaranteed that theadopti<strong>on</strong> of the favoured instituti<strong>on</strong>al and policymix will bring higher GDP growth, studies showthat differences in policy and policy implementati<strong>on</strong>are reflected in dramatically different rates ofgrowth of GDP per capita achieved. Appropriateregulatory and instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment has beenfound to be the single most important elementin an ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth strategy. Even thougha country’s level of skills, especially technicalskills, is also str<strong>on</strong>gly correlated with per capitaec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, interventi<strong>on</strong>s to improve thenati<strong>on</strong>al regulatory and instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment213


within which business operates offer far morerapid impact scenarios than those based <strong>on</strong> l<strong>on</strong>gerterm educati<strong>on</strong> and skills strategiesA Mapping of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omies 40Although, the studies that describe countrylevel patterns and changes have at best beensketchy, given the complexity of measuring thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omies precisely, they are certainlyindicative. Over the last fifteen years or so, thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector in Sub-Saharan Africa has apparentlyincreased from about two-thirds to nearlythree-quarters of n<strong>on</strong>-agricultural employment. 41Street vending predominates, with women traders<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming the majority in many of the countries inthe regi<strong>on</strong>. Former retailing establishments oftenencourage in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy operators to expandtheir markets to low income groups and ruralareas who can be reached most easily by itineranttraders and street vendors.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises are small-scale enterpriseswith 80 percent classified as a <strong>on</strong>e-pers<strong>on</strong> business.Businesses with more that <strong>on</strong>e pers<strong>on</strong> weremainly found to be in transportati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>.For women in this regi<strong>on</strong>, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy presents 92 percent of the total job opportunitiesoutside of agriculture compared to 71percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> men. Almost 75 percent of these jobsare per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med as self-employed and own-accountworkers, and <strong>on</strong>ly 5 percent as paid employees.Most small scale enterprises are without a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malestablishment: over 33 percent of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malactivities take place within or beside the homeof the business operator; 20 percent are withouta fixed locati<strong>on</strong>; 10 percent are at a market, and10 percent are in the street or in an open space.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> major sources of livelihoods, especially<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women engaged in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal activities (foodprocessing, handicrafts, hawking and vending),have been affected by trade liberalisati<strong>on</strong> and bycross-border trading. Cross-border trading is verysignificant in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and is prevalentin South Africa and West Africa. For instance,a large number of temporary immigrants purchasegoods in South Africa to take back to their owncountries <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sale. While normally the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maltrade is within the regi<strong>on</strong> itself, traders from WestAfrica travel as far as Dubai and China to purchasehigher quality goods that are cheap. 42 Also,vendors in Africa now have opportunities to link upwith bigger enterprises and transnati<strong>on</strong>al corporati<strong>on</strong>sto become a part of their value chain. 43In Latin America, urban in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employmentincreased from 52 percent in 1990 to 58 percentin 1997 as a proporti<strong>on</strong> of the total urbanemployment. 44 Not surprisingly, the increase wasalso observed in employment in micro and smallenterprises as well as growth in self-employment.A proporti<strong>on</strong> of self-employment or own-accountworkers is an indicator of low job growth in the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and a high rate of employmentcreati<strong>on</strong> in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Self-employmentrepresents nearly 32 percent of totaln<strong>on</strong>-agricultural employment worldwide, with 44percent in Latin America. 45 In poor countries likeBangladesh and Pakistan, the proporti<strong>on</strong> of selfemploymentaccounts <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> nearly 70 percent ofthe total employment.In the transiti<strong>on</strong> countries of Central and EasternEurope and the countries of the Comm<strong>on</strong>wealthof Independent States (CIS), the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyranges from subsistence farming, petty trade,undeclared and unregistered labour, unregulatedand unlicensed enterprises, the shuttle trade withneighbouring countries, to tax evasi<strong>on</strong>. With thetransiti<strong>on</strong> of the regi<strong>on</strong> to a market ec<strong>on</strong>omy, thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy has expanded rapidly becauseof ec<strong>on</strong>omics and social trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>s, closureof many state- owned enterprises, increasedprivatisati<strong>on</strong>, labour retrenchment and collapse of214


social insurance, and need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>al, businessand labour re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that have lacked en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementand failed to keep in touch with changingec<strong>on</strong>omic realities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> expansi<strong>on</strong> of manufacturing and industryhas led to a relative decline in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy in China, Japan, the Republic of Koreaand Singapore. While the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy hadalso declined from 60 to 57 percent in Thailandfrom 1980 and 1994 because of the ec<strong>on</strong>omicboom, with the effect of the ec<strong>on</strong>omic recessi<strong>on</strong>of 1997 it grew again to 60 percent. 46 Althoughec<strong>on</strong>omic recessi<strong>on</strong> leads to an increase in‘survivalist’ ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities suggesting thepoverty mitigating role of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,ec<strong>on</strong>omic prosperity has also been directly relatedto an increase in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, asin Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, because of increased opportunitiesand the ability of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises to resp<strong>on</strong>dto new market opportunities. An expansi<strong>on</strong>of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer circumstancesreflects marginalizati<strong>on</strong> of ec<strong>on</strong>omic activitiescharacterised by low productivity, low incomesand low standards of living. 47 On the otherhand, expansi<strong>on</strong> of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy duringan ec<strong>on</strong>omic boom is related to the expediencyof bypassing over-bearing bureaucratic processesand business practices that can c<strong>on</strong>strain firmsin the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy from resp<strong>on</strong>ding quickly tomarket signals and increasing demand.Women in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omyWorldwide, women’s share of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyemployment has remained between 60 percentand 80 percent. Moreover, the number of femalesin the labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce is c<strong>on</strong>tinuously <strong>on</strong> the rise andwomen in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy most probablynumber much more than reflected in availablestatistics. (Girls, too, would be am<strong>on</strong>g their numbers.)<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y comprise most of the unpaid labour,are often home-based workers, and thus fall easilythrough gaps in enumerati<strong>on</strong> as data and statistics<strong>on</strong> household level is still difficult to measure. Inmany countries, women are also drawn to the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy because they lack the right to ownand inherit property and are there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e obstructedfrom activity in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, as they d<strong>on</strong>ot have assets to use as security <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> credits, etc.A statistical snapshot of women in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy around the world reveals: 481) In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment is generally a largersource of employment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women than <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> menin the developing world. Other than in the MiddleEast and North Africa, where 42 percentof women workers are in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment,60 percent or more of women workers in thedeveloping world are in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment(outside agriculture). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> comparative figures<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment, as share of n<strong>on</strong>-agriculturalemployment by sex and regi<strong>on</strong>, areas follow: in sub-Saharan Africa, 84 percentof women workers compared to 63 percent ofmen workers; in Latin America, 58 percent ofwomen workers, 48 percent of men workers,and in Asia, 73 percent of women to 70 percentof men.2) Although women’s labour-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce participati<strong>on</strong>rates are lower than men’s, the limited dataavailable points to the importance of women inhome-based work and street vending in developingcountries: 30-90 percent of street vendors,except in societies that restrict women’smobility; 35-80 per-cent of all home-basedworkers, including both self-employed andhome workers; and 80 percent or more of homeworkers — industrial outworkers who work athome).3) Although women’s labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce participati<strong>on</strong>rates are lower than men’s, women representthe vast majority of part-time workers in many215


developed countries. In 1998, women were60 percent or more of part-time workers in allOECD countries reporting data. Women’s shareof part-time work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> specific countries was ashigh as 98 percent in Sweden, 80 percent inthe United Kingdom, and 68 percent in bothJapan and the United States.Indigenous Peoples and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinessesAlthough the c<strong>on</strong>cept of social exclusi<strong>on</strong> hasgained wide currency, over 370 milli<strong>on</strong> indigenouspeoples c<strong>on</strong>tinue to be marginalized fromthe benefits of mainstream social and ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment. Indigenous peoples are over-representedam<strong>on</strong>g the poor in over 70 countries.Lacking secure property rights hinders indigenouspeoples in obtaining compensati<strong>on</strong> fromgovernment in cases of evicti<strong>on</strong> and displacement.Usually, this is due to lack of evidence tosupport their property rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also face hugebarriers in obtaining legal protecti<strong>on</strong> (throughen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement opportunities), access to resourcesand wealth creati<strong>on</strong>. Due to past experiencesof bias and discriminati<strong>on</strong>, many indigenouspeoples <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>go <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal justice systems; also, legalaid services are often not provided to those livingoutside the mainstream justice system. Lack oftitle to property is another barrier to ec<strong>on</strong>omicempowerment. Traditi<strong>on</strong>al property rights systemsare being eroded as a result of neo-liberal,macro-ec<strong>on</strong>omic policies. Indigenous peoplesmust there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e resort to finding employment inoccupati<strong>on</strong>s that are not <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally paid, as mightbe the case in rotati<strong>on</strong>al farming, fishing andweaving. Illiteracy and impoverishment furtherlimit employment opportunities in low paid jobs.Indigenous women carry the burden of reproductivework, domestic work, child care and workingin the field.Distinct cultural identity and values: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenouspeople’s perspectives <strong>on</strong> property, povertyand development are different from mainstreamthinking and are not based solely <strong>on</strong> a marketcash-based ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Many indigenous societiesexchange value (rather than m<strong>on</strong>ey) by <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms ofbarter, gift exchange, and other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of reciprocalexchange. A better understanding of these‘principles of reciprocity’ would be needed tounderpin the work of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>. This maypose a number of binary oppositi<strong>on</strong>s, many ofwhich may be challenged and c<strong>on</strong>tested, including:spirituality vs. rati<strong>on</strong>ality, collectivity vs.individuality (competiti<strong>on</strong>, intellectual propertyclaims), sustainability vs. optimal productivity,traditi<strong>on</strong>al knowledge (e.g. trial and error) vs.empirical scientific methodology, subsistencevs. commerciality or markets, custom vs. state,rights vs. poverty, and inclusi<strong>on</strong> vs. exclusi<strong>on</strong> (orassimilati<strong>on</strong> vs. integrati<strong>on</strong>).Indigenous peoples often employ innovativemethods to subsist, using traditi<strong>on</strong>al knowledgesystems. With the <strong>on</strong>set of globalisati<strong>on</strong>, it atfirst appeared that a new envir<strong>on</strong>ment would beopened to developing new approaches, but barriersto entrepreneurship remain.Micro-credit and micro-finance instituti<strong>on</strong>s areoften the <strong>on</strong>ly source of capital <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenouspeoples and women in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and homebasedsectors. However, indigenous peoples’percepti<strong>on</strong>s of credit and loans are often compromisedin the interests of entering the globalec<strong>on</strong>omy. Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to promote innovati<strong>on</strong> andentrepreneurship in indigenous peoples’ territoriesshould seek to understand and assessthe systems of exchanging value in the society,sometimes based <strong>on</strong> complex kinship, culturaland other social networks.216


Box 1 Empowering Indigenouspeoples throughEntrepreneurship<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO-INDISCO Programme was launched in thePhilippines in 1994 in collaborati<strong>on</strong> with the PhilippineGovernment. It is a multi-bilateral technicalcooperati<strong>on</strong> aimed at strengthening the self-relianceof indigenous and tribal peoples through entrepreneurialactivity. It has facilitated the operati<strong>on</strong> of 12pilot projects in different parts of the country, whichinvolve indigenous communities in various stagesof development. Financial and technical assistancehas been provided to indigenous communities toengage in entrepreneurship.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main window of opportunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> income andemployment generati<strong>on</strong> opened to community memberswas the Revolving Loan Fund, which providesassistance to groups and individuals <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theirlivelihoods activities. Together with skills training <strong>on</strong>a particular trade the community wanted to pursue,plus appropriate equipment bought from projectfunds, members of several indigenous communitiesmanaged to improve their market access and ec<strong>on</strong>omicstatus. Twelve communities with a combinedpopulati<strong>on</strong> of approximately 90,000 people havebenefi ted directly or indirectly from these projects.An estimated 2,500 jobs in agriculture, traditi<strong>on</strong>alhandicraft, fi shery, weaving and community serviceswere created. As a result of the new revenue-generatingactivities, the income levels of partnercommunities have increased by an average of 44percent. In recent years, the ILO has been providingtechnical assistance to some projects fundedthrough the Small Grant Fund from the Embassy ofFinland. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fund has supported various projectsproposed by the Indigenous communities.Source: ILOEmpowering In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal BusinessesClearly, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal business ec<strong>on</strong>omy also links<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sectors to c<strong>on</strong>sumers. In fact it providesmany low and middle-income employees of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector with goods and services and c<strong>on</strong>tributesto ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth,while a necessary c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>, is not a sufficientc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> creating productive employment andpoverty reducti<strong>on</strong>. As discussed earlier, an increasein ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth does not usually resultin the alleviati<strong>on</strong> of an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy or thetransiti<strong>on</strong> from in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal unless it alsobrings greater equity. A positive outcome wouldreflect an approach that regards people living inpoverty as creators of growth rather than merelyas recipients of benefits. 49 We should, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,focus <strong>on</strong> empowering the poor and the disadvantaged,whether as self-employed producersand entrepreneurs or as employees of a firm. Itis important that these ec<strong>on</strong>omic actors participatefully and <strong>on</strong> an equal basis in the ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopmentSome of the critical barriers faced by firms inthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy include limited humanand working capital, limited access to markets,goods and services and to financial and businesssupport services, obsolete technology, complexand burdensome government regulati<strong>on</strong>s with pooren<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement, lack of ec<strong>on</strong>omic infrastructure anda poor supply of public services. Given the impedimentsto operate businesses in most developingcountries, the opportunity costs of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malityappear to be much lower compared to operating<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally. It is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e not surprising that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malnetworks also coordinate many transacti<strong>on</strong>sam<strong>on</strong>g the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises. Emphasis must fall<strong>on</strong> improving the business envir<strong>on</strong>ment, and in amanner that it is particularly beneficial <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> enterpriseat local level, including the rural areas. Forinstance, India’s ec<strong>on</strong>omic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, which alsocover the business envir<strong>on</strong>ment, have generallyfocused <strong>on</strong> the corporate and the organised sectorthat provides employment to nearly three percentof the country’s work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce, with another three to217


four percent employed in the public sector andgovernment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> balance, or roughly 93 percentof the work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce, which is essentially the self-organisedin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, remains untouched bythose ec<strong>on</strong>omic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. 50Accordingly, it is important to improve theec<strong>on</strong>omic governance structure that could allowsmaller <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises to grow with greaterefficiency, productivity and quality working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.It is equally necessary to facilitate theproblems faced by in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises in accessingproducts offered by financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s,such as the incorporati<strong>on</strong> of security insuranceand the establishment of limited liability instituti<strong>on</strong>sthat might encourage high return-high riskinvestment. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises also need to besensitised to the requirements <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improving employmentand working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s so that they areable to access dual labour regulati<strong>on</strong>s and safetynets in meeting part of their own labour c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>swhile sustaining the business and generatingdecent employment. 51Similarly, efficiency am<strong>on</strong>g the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprisesshould be improved comprehensively and in anintegrated manner by en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing the rule of law.This would cover property rights and the reducti<strong>on</strong>of corrupti<strong>on</strong> by lowering transacti<strong>on</strong> costsof various activities. It would include reducingentry and operating <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal costs, reducing growthbarriers and implementing cost-efficient andproficient policies, guidelines and procedures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of compliance. If a <strong>on</strong>e-stop shopis a soluti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> reducing registrati<strong>on</strong> proceduresand costs, then it is vital that such facilities areorganised and available at different levels (local,municipal, district, nati<strong>on</strong>al and regi<strong>on</strong>al).This would not <strong>on</strong>ly facilitate the availability ofrelevant in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, but would also be a disincentiveto operate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally if cost was the solerati<strong>on</strong>ale <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> such an acti<strong>on</strong>.Awell-structured tax system that is understandableand transparent would also dissuadefirms from adopting the inefficiencies ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality simply to avoid taxes. Also, if locallevies translate into fees <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> enhancing access tocommunity resources as well as public serviceswith greater accountability, the attractiveness andlower opportunity cost of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector woulddiminish significantly.It would also be helpful to introduce propertyrights registrati<strong>on</strong>, c<strong>on</strong>tract en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement mechanismsand clear policy guidelines to encouragemarket participati<strong>on</strong> of street vendors, etc., ina manner that is participative, and incorporatesin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and popular rules. By bringing diversegovernance structures within the purview of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal judicial system in a manner that is accessibleand simple, it would increase the reach ofrule of law to all business operators and encouragethe efficient creati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward and backward linkages.Given suitable c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, including provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>capacity development, vocati<strong>on</strong>al training, andskill building, many in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises mayef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tlessly glide into <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal <strong>on</strong>es. This empowermentprogramme has to be an integral comp<strong>on</strong>entof poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> strategies using incentivesbased <strong>on</strong> participati<strong>on</strong>, a level playing field ofregulati<strong>on</strong>s, and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cements thereof that, interalia, enhances efficient, af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable and reliableaccess to public infrastructure services.While legal identity has been linked to a greateraccess to basic goods and services and opportunities,it could catalyse inclusive development<strong>on</strong>ce it becomes a c<strong>on</strong>stituent of a larger re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>magenda. So, legal identity must be internalisedin policies and acti<strong>on</strong>s that target the integrati<strong>on</strong>of markets of the poor with other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal markets,thereby enabling them to meet the unmet de-218


mand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable financial services. But, in theabsence of legal documents, it is very unlikelythat emphasis <strong>on</strong> legal identity would reduceexclusi<strong>on</strong>. 52 Accordingly, the challenge to comprehensivelyaddress the inter-related comp<strong>on</strong>entsof the c<strong>on</strong>tinuum from the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malend of the ec<strong>on</strong>omy is not technological; it is instructuring instituti<strong>on</strong>s, capacities, incentivesand regulati<strong>on</strong>s to provide certainty to ec<strong>on</strong>omicexchange and there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e to equitable ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth. 53issues highlighted in this secti<strong>on</strong>, which also providedan overview of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omies aroundthe globe. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> next secti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> legal identity andbusiness rights discusses, am<strong>on</strong>g other issues,the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an effective enabling envir<strong>on</strong>ment,regulatory regime, commercial law and good ec<strong>on</strong>omicgovernance that is required <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> businessto operate with equitable ec<strong>on</strong>omic rights andwith guarantees of greater accountability in thegovernment’s ability to issue laws with the capacityto implement and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce them.Ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth draws up<strong>on</strong> activities that arecomplex, fluid and geographically dispersed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>yrequire an elaborate and ever evolving divisi<strong>on</strong> oflabour ranging from owners of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises, producers, managers, and theiremployees, who are an integral comp<strong>on</strong>ent of thevalue chain. Such a large-scale divisi<strong>on</strong> of labourrequires state-like instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementof laws and c<strong>on</strong>tracts 54 and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> its efficientsustainability. Although the government takes thelead in creating regulati<strong>on</strong>s, it is important to engageother stakeholders, including the poor peopleas ec<strong>on</strong>omic actors, as well as NGOs, localpublic governance structures, and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal labourassociati<strong>on</strong>s. This would ensure ownership by allrelevant actors and create inexpensive approachesto en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce compliance with the regulati<strong>on</strong>s. Itis the inclusive partnerships and a shared agendabetween small and large firms, governments at alllevels, civil society and the development agenciesthat will unlock new opportunities. 55To Sum UpIncreasing poverty is a key reas<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> growth ofthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and a main cause of theblossoming of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises strugglingto overcome legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>al hurdles thatmake it difficult prevent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> businesses to becomeor stay <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are some of the broad219


3.Business Rights:Unlocking Barriers/C<strong>on</strong>straints to EmpowerIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> adverse effects up<strong>on</strong> the poor of living undera system of unequal opportunities of representati<strong>on</strong>,political voice and power tend to reproducethemselves over time and across generati<strong>on</strong>s,setting into moti<strong>on</strong> a classical poverty trap fromwhich relatively few can escape. In this chapter,the positi<strong>on</strong> is taken that promoting businessrights in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy could helpto unlock pent-up talents and energies am<strong>on</strong>gthe working poor and create an efficient andinclusive private sector. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> view is that a keyto improving the quality of life of the poor andthe disadvantaged is the creati<strong>on</strong> of an efficientprivate sector with a sound domestic macroenvir<strong>on</strong>ment, and replete with trade policies, instituti<strong>on</strong>alfoundati<strong>on</strong>s and adequate capacity tomaximise benefits within a broader macro globalenvir<strong>on</strong>ment. Such a creati<strong>on</strong> would dependup<strong>on</strong> good ec<strong>on</strong>omic governance, en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceablelaws and regulati<strong>on</strong>s, effective instituti<strong>on</strong>s, practicesand dedicated people to support inclusiveand equitable development of the domesticprivate sector.This chapter there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e argues <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> effective andenabling envir<strong>on</strong>ments, a regulatory regime,commercial law and good ec<strong>on</strong>omic governance.It is expected that this process will empower thepoor to use law and legal tools to prevail overpoverty, while persuading government to equitablyen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce policies and regulati<strong>on</strong>s. This wouldrein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce the role of the civil society in implementinggreater accountability of all actors andat all levels. Sound ec<strong>on</strong>omic governance is builtup<strong>on</strong> principles of equity and equality of opportunities.With public policies and supportingacti<strong>on</strong>, assurances could be given about accessto and distributi<strong>on</strong> of assets, ec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities,and political voice participati<strong>on</strong> in decisi<strong>on</strong>making— all of which can help to promote thecreati<strong>on</strong> of sustainable enterprises. This is thepath to address the often-heard demands to ‘levelthe playing field.’It is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e essential to build up<strong>on</strong> and refinethe above issues in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the work of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> and re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the development agendaby broadening the discussi<strong>on</strong> of business rightsand the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy in a comprehensivemanner that goes bey<strong>on</strong>d <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> per se.In other words, the legal empowerment of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal business can generate sustainable livelihoods<strong>on</strong>ly by first addressing the c<strong>on</strong>straints andbarriers that stifle their productive potential andencourage them to have a voice in all aspects ofpolicy making, implementing and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing andhave the ability to work with governments andother stakeholders to create new rights, capacities,and opportunities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> core set of legal en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement comp<strong>on</strong>entsare presented in Box 2, below.Empowerment has to be specific to c<strong>on</strong>text,the social reality of different groups, locati<strong>on</strong>etc. Policymakers and practiti<strong>on</strong>ers must tailorthe various elements from the framework to meetlocal circumstances. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, below, dem<strong>on</strong>strateshow LE could address the specific c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sof street vendors.Different levels of commercial rights are appropriateto the circumstances of different typesof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses: notably, street vendors,in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal manufacturers, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal transport providers,and small farmers. Commercial rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses can be stratified as follows:• Basic commercial rights: right to work, in-220


Box 2 Unlocking Barriers: <strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms to Empower In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses1) <strong>Legal</strong> and bureaucratic procedures that allow in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maloperators or businesses to operate:• Simplifi ed registrati<strong>on</strong> procedures;• Simplifi ed licensing and permit procedures;• Identifi cati<strong>on</strong> devices, including: ID cards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> individualoperators, and business identificati<strong>on</strong>;• Legislati<strong>on</strong> — e.g., municipal by-laws — that allowstreet vendors to operate in public spaces.2) Appropriate legal frameworks that enshrine the followingas ec<strong>on</strong>omic rights:• Access to finance, raw material, and productmarkets at fair prices ;• Access to transport and communicati<strong>on</strong> infrastructure;• Access to improved skills and technology;• Access to business development services;• Access to business incentive and trade promoti<strong>on</strong>packages: tax deferrals, subsidies, trade fairs.3) <strong>Legal</strong> property rights:• Private land;• Intellectual property.4) Use rights to public resources and appropriatez<strong>on</strong>ing regulati<strong>on</strong>s:• Use rights to urban public land;• Use to comm<strong>on</strong> and public resources: pastures,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests, and waterways;• appropriate z<strong>on</strong>ing regulati<strong>on</strong>s where governing andunder what c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators or businessescan operate in central business districts,suburban areas, and/or industrial z<strong>on</strong>es.5) Appropriate legal frameworks and standards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>what in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators and businesses are allowed tobuy and sell:• Appropriate laws and regulati<strong>on</strong>s regarding whatare legal vs. illegal goods and services;• Appropriate product and process standards: <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, public health and sanitati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns restreet food;• Marketing licenses <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> products and services.6) Appropriate legal tools to govern the transacti<strong>on</strong>and c<strong>on</strong>tractual relati<strong>on</strong>ships of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators orbusinesses including:• Bargaining and negotiating mechanisms/power;• <strong>Legal</strong> and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable c<strong>on</strong>tracts;• Grievance mechanisms;• C<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms;• Possibility of issuing shares, right to issue shares;• Right to advertise and protect brands and trademarks.7) <strong>Legal</strong> rights and mechanisms to provide in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maloperators and businesses with the following:• Temporary unemployment relief;• Insurance of various kinds, including of land, house,equipment, and other means of producti<strong>on</strong>;• Bankruptcy rules and default rules;• Limited liability, asset and capital protecti<strong>on</strong>;• Capital withdrawal and transfer rules.8) <strong>Legal</strong> right <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators and businessesto join or <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m organisati<strong>on</strong>s, legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> of suchand legal right of the organisati<strong>on</strong>s to be representedin relevant policymaking and rule-setting instituti<strong>on</strong>s• Membership in mainstream business associati<strong>on</strong>s;• Membership in guilds or other associati<strong>on</strong>s ofsimilar types of entrepreneurs;• Representati<strong>on</strong> in relevant planning andrule-setting bodies.221


Street VendorsComm<strong>on</strong> issues and challenges faceInsecure place of work due to competiti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> urban space.Capital <strong>on</strong> unfair terms due to dependence <strong>on</strong> wholesale tradersUncertain quantity, quality, and price of goods due to dependence<strong>on</strong> wholesale traders.Lack of infrastructure i.e. shelter, water, sanitati<strong>on</strong>.Ambiguous legal status leading to harassment.Evicti<strong>on</strong>s and bribes.Negative public image.What <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment can do <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themSecure vending sites.Provide access to capital <strong>on</strong> fair terms: a loan producttailored to their daily need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> working capital.Boost bargaining power with wholesale traders.Infrastructure services at vending sites i.e. shelter,water, sanitati<strong>on</strong>.Licence to sell issue identity cards.Freedom from harassment, evicti<strong>on</strong>s, and bribes.Positive public image.cluding right to vend; right to a work space• Intermediary commercial rights: right togovernment incentives and support includingprocurement and the right to publicinfrastructure• Advanced commercial rights: those that arerelevant <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> larger, more advanced in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se rights would then apply in different ways todifferent types of street vendors including:• Those who sell fruit and vegetables: theyneed basic and intermediate commercialrights;• Those who sell cooked food: they need basiccommercial rights and intermediate commercialrights but also need to be regulated<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public safety c<strong>on</strong>cerns;• Those who sell small domestically-producedmanufactured goods need basic and intermediatecommercial rights and may als<strong>on</strong>eed to be regulated to ensure the goods arenot pirated;• Those who sell more valuable imported manufacturedgoods need basic and intermediatecommercial rights and may also need tobe regulated to ensure that the goods arenot smuggled or pirated.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> illustrati<strong>on</strong>s shown above would suggestc<strong>on</strong>cerns about advanced commercial rights areessentially relevant <strong>on</strong>ly after the basic and intermediatecommercial rights are taken care of.Barriers and C<strong>on</strong>straints to BusinessRightsAddressing the issue of legally empoweringin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses is critical to unlocking theproductive potential of individuals, communitiesand countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are significant barriers tobasic business rights, including the cost of, anddifficulty with repsect to accessing and obtaininglicenses or permits, the cost of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming legalentities or, in some countries, even of registeringas a pers<strong>on</strong> engaged in commerce. And, and ofcourse, there is also the weight of taxati<strong>on</strong>.Cost-benefit analysis is influenced also by n<strong>on</strong>-legalcosts. For example, if business people do nothave their basic human rights respected, the costof doing business rises. If the level of educati<strong>on</strong>makes counting difficult, that is a cost. If the levelof healthcare prevents people from using theirhuman capital, that, too is a cost. And outside theclassic human rights rubric, if public transporta-222


ti<strong>on</strong> is inadequate or the roads are largely impassable,that too is an additi<strong>on</strong>al cost. And all thesecosts are effective barriers to exit from the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, because they make all other costs,including legal costs, that much more <strong>on</strong>erous.Below is an elaborati<strong>on</strong> of implicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thosecurrently doing business in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally.<strong>Legal</strong>, Regulatory, and AdministrativeBarriersRegulatory barriers comprise inappropriate orrigid requirements and stem from a governmentpolicymaking envir<strong>on</strong>ment that normally wishesto have a total c<strong>on</strong>trol either <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a political or socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omicagenda. Many developing countriesare emerging from a history of heavy-handedregulati<strong>on</strong>, with approvals required <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> even thesmallest activity, and authority overly centralisedand inflexible. This means they are hampered bythe legacy of a heavily regulated ec<strong>on</strong>omy and acommand and c<strong>on</strong>trol approach to administrati<strong>on</strong>and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement. Poor quality law-making overthe years has created a tangle of complex andinc<strong>on</strong>sistent laws that present a daunting regulatoryhurdle to the would-be <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprise. Assuch, the regulatory systems of these countriesare not well developed to support a flourishingmarket ec<strong>on</strong>omy that will create growth and<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal jobs. A study 56 carried out in 2002 foundthat the costs and barriers imposed by regulati<strong>on</strong>in developing countries are not <strong>on</strong>ly higherthan they were in the developed world when itembarked <strong>on</strong> industrialisati<strong>on</strong>, but are higher insome cases than in the advanced countries today.Taking business entry costs as a proxy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> allregulatory costs, the report suggested that thesecosts in Africa (94%), in relati<strong>on</strong> to GDP percapita, are much higher than those in other partsof the world — Central Europe (67%), IndustrialSouth Asia (19.80%), and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> many advancedcountries (3%).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank study <strong>on</strong> doing business usingindicators such as those in FIgure 3, 57 establishedclearly the correlati<strong>on</strong> between the ease of doingbusiness and the size of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Two methods were used to produce the ranking —<strong>on</strong>e involved averaging out a country’s per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>manceacross the indicators, and the other used the rawvalues of indicators. Both regressi<strong>on</strong>s showed thatthere is a statistically significant correlati<strong>on</strong> betweena country’s overall per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance <strong>on</strong> the DoingBusiness indicators and the size of its in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malFigure 3 Regulatory Burdens Impacting <strong>on</strong> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises (World Bank, 2005)Starting a BusinessNumber of ProceduresTime (days)CostMinimum CapitalRegistering PropertyNumber of ProceduresTimeCostHiring and Firing of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ersDiffi culty of hiringRigidity of hoursDiffi culty of fi ringRigidity of employmentFiring costsGetting CreditCost to create collateral<strong>Legal</strong> rights of borrowers and lendersCredit in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>Public registry coveragePrivate bureau coverage223


Box 3 Most Difficult Places toDo Business(by specific category)Starting a Business• 17 Procedures in Uganda/Paraguay,• 694 days in Suriname• 1,194 percent of income per capita required as costin Sierra Le<strong>on</strong>• 4,233 percent of income per capita minimum capitalrequired in SyriaDealing with Licenses• 186 Procedures in Egypt• 668 days in Iran• 5,869 percent of income per capita required as costin M<strong>on</strong>tenegroRegistering Property• 16 Procedures in Nigeria• 683 days in Haiti• 28 percent of property value as cost in SyriaEmploying <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers• On diffi culty of hiring index (100=worst) in Morocco,Nigeria and Tanzania• On diffi culty of fi ring index (100=worst) in Boliviaand Egypt• 329 weeks of salary as fi ring cost in Sierra Le<strong>on</strong>eTrading Across Borders• 16 number of documents required to export inZambia• 20 number of documents required to import inRwandaGetting Credits• 0 Strength of legal rights in Cambodia, from an Index0-10 (0 is the worst)• 0 Depth of credit in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> in 48 countries, froman Index 0-10 (0 is the worst)Paying Taxes• 130 times payment per year in Uzbekistan• 291 percent of profi t as total tax rate in GambiaClosing a Business• Takes up to 10 years in India• Cost (percent of estate): 76 in Lao PDRSource: World Bank: Doing Business 2007(prepared by Mahmood Iqbal)ec<strong>on</strong>omy; a worse envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> doing businesscorrelates with a larger in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>analysis also examined the relati<strong>on</strong>ship betweenthe individual measures of ease of doing businessand the size of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank has c<strong>on</strong>ducted a comprehensivestudy, 58 in identifying and quantifyingthe cost of barriers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all regi<strong>on</strong>s of the worldand individual countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> extreme cases aresummarissed in Box 3.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank study also shows that regulatoryenvir<strong>on</strong>ment and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality are highly correlated:the greater the difficulty in business operati<strong>on</strong>,the larger the size of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector. In otherwords, barriers or extent of difficulties in doingbusiness <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce many operators to take the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malroute.Administrative barriers are the bureaucraticrequirements that flow from regulati<strong>on</strong>s, their implementati<strong>on</strong>and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement. A regulati<strong>on</strong> maybe well-designed, proporti<strong>on</strong>ate and efficient, butits true effect <strong>on</strong> enterprises comes from the wayin which it is administered. Administrative barriersare the hassle that dissuades in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprisesfrom wanting to interact with governmentofficials; 59 they include excessive paperwork; civilservice inefficiency leading to delays in decisi<strong>on</strong>-making;low levels of civil service capacity,i.e. poor skills levels so that mistakes are made,and too few people and access points providingservices; inaccessibility, as when there is too littledelegati<strong>on</strong> to the fr<strong>on</strong>t-line and decisi<strong>on</strong>s have tobe referred up to the management chain; generalbureaucratic obstructi<strong>on</strong> (perhaps stemming frominherent distrust of the private sector by officials)c<strong>on</strong>tributing to delays, and abuse of positi<strong>on</strong>(linked to corrupti<strong>on</strong>).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> time and m<strong>on</strong>ey spent complying with governmentregulati<strong>on</strong>s impose significant transac-224


Figure 4 Regulatory Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malityGreater ease of doing business is associated with less <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malityIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector (share of GDP)HigherImplied cut in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector from improving tothe top <strong>on</strong> ease of doing business40%30%20%}Implied cutImpliedshare aftercutLower10%Least difficultMost difficultCountries ranked by ease of doing business, quintilesLeast difficultNote: Relati<strong>on</strong>ships are significant at 1% level and remain significant when c<strong>on</strong>trolling <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> income per capita.Source: World Bank (2005)Most difficultti<strong>on</strong> costs <strong>on</strong> businesses. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the directcost of payments, such as licensing fees, alsorepresents a significant cost of doing business.C<strong>on</strong>versely, payments made to avoid detecti<strong>on</strong>of n<strong>on</strong>-compliance, or payoffs to government officialsare the costs of operating in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsector. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> regulati<strong>on</strong>s imposed <strong>on</strong> business fallinto several categories. Some regulati<strong>on</strong>s governingbusiness start-up raise the costs of enteringthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector, others govern <strong>on</strong>going businessactivity, and additi<strong>on</strong>al regulati<strong>on</strong>s are dictated bythe central authority or by regi<strong>on</strong>al or municipalgovernments. Furthermore, small businesses facegovernment-imposed costs in the areas of labourpractices, payroll charges, health and safety standards,taxati<strong>on</strong>, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign trade.Governance Issues: In many developing countries,corrupti<strong>on</strong> and rent-seeking reduce in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>flows and weaken c<strong>on</strong>tract en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement, reducingec<strong>on</strong>omic activity, especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign investment.Every major study <strong>on</strong> barriers to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> andindeed <strong>on</strong> barriers to growth generally, refers tothe problem of corrupti<strong>on</strong>.Often it is not the financial cost itself thatcreates the largest transacti<strong>on</strong> cost obstacleto setting up a small business, but rather thetime and energy required to navigate the bureaucraticmaze, al<strong>on</strong>g with the opportunity costsinvolved. A well-known example was provided byHernando de Soto when he measured the cost ofestablishing a small garment manufacturing enterprisein Lima, Peru. He found that it requiredmany different steps over an extended periodof time to set up a small <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal manufacturingcompany. 60 Although Peru has substantially re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>medand simplified the process of setting upa small business, de Soto’s overall c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>sremain as valid <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> many other Latin Americancountries today as they did in Peru in the late1980s. This is why entrepreneurs frequentlyresort to bribes or professi<strong>on</strong>al ‘fixers’ in order toexpedite the registrati<strong>on</strong> and licensing process.Fixers’ fees to establish a company range fromUS$600 to US$800 to establish a company inmost Latin American countries; they rise quitesharply as the size of the firm increases.225


Case Study:Ukraine and Private Business Development<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> dimensi<strong>on</strong> of the problem: A 1999 surveyof businesses and households suggested that,there were 3.073 milli<strong>on</strong> businesses in Ukraine,of which 2.651 milli<strong>on</strong> (86%) had no employees.Comparing the official figures of smallfirms (with fewer than 50 employees) suggestedthat over 80 percent of these 2.651 milli<strong>on</strong>, ortwo milli<strong>on</strong> businesses were unregistered andin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal, which is, strictly speaking,, illegal, inUkrainian terms.Key problem: Corrupti<strong>on</strong> and other rent-seekingbehaviour. It is widely agreed that the biggestissue <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ukrainianbusinesses is its unpredictability. Regulati<strong>on</strong>sare often c<strong>on</strong>fusing or unclear, many regulatoryactivities lack a comprehensive legislativebasis, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> is lacking and procedures areunnecessarily complex. Rules change frequently— <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example there were 34 amendments tokey tax laws in 2004. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> lack of clear and accuratein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> businesses <strong>on</strong> the currentstate of the law assists rent seeking behaviourby corrupt officials.Inspecti<strong>on</strong>s are still the biggest problem facedby Ukrainian business, but the problem appearsto be decreasing slowly. In 2001, 94 percent offirms were inspected at some time during theyear (a figure which had declined by 20 percentsince 2000) with the average firm receiving11.7 inspecti<strong>on</strong>s. In 2004, 78 percent of firmssurveyed were inspected. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> typical smallfirm spent 22 days dealing with inspecti<strong>on</strong>s in2001, compared to 27 days in 2000. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re isno comparable figure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2004.In 2001, 40 percent of all firms surveyed madeunofficial payments to inspecting bodies, and28 percent in 2002. In 2004, this figure appearedto have dropped to 20 percent.Key problem remaining: Current legislativeframeworks are too complex, c<strong>on</strong>fused andscattered. As a result of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and d<strong>on</strong>or assistanceover several years, the 140 steps thatbusinesses had to take <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> full registrati<strong>on</strong> havenow been decreased to 70. Needless to say, thisnumber still is very high.(Source: A Review of the Development of the Private Sector in Ukrainesince1998, and an Evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of DFID. DFID 2006)Corrupti<strong>on</strong> deters <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> as businesses stayoff registries and tax rolls in order to minimisec<strong>on</strong>tact with corrupt public officials. One broadstudy of 69 countries found a direct link betweendecreasing corrupti<strong>on</strong> and an increasing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. 61 In a study of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector inUkraine, 82 percent of businesses believed thatbribes to officials were necessary in order to c<strong>on</strong>tinueto operate. 62 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> smallest businesses suffermost from paying bribes, because these sumsdecrease the paltry profits made by thm.Financial Barriers: Financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s depend<strong>on</strong> the credibility of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal documentati<strong>on</strong> toprovide the security and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceability necessaryto extend credit. As in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessescomm<strong>on</strong>ly do not possess land title or a standingrelati<strong>on</strong>ship with a bank, the most prevalent<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of loan guarantee, real estate and fiduciarycollateral, are generally unavailable. Formallenders typically require borrowers to providefinancial statements and credible documentati<strong>on</strong>related to the lender’s recent operati<strong>on</strong>s (bank226


statements, invoices, etc.). Accordingly, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malentrepreneurs unaccustomed to separating theirbusiness and pers<strong>on</strong>al transacti<strong>on</strong>s or recordingand maintaining the firm’s in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, or whouse in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal suppliers who are unable to providedocumentati<strong>on</strong> as solicited by the lender, will berequired to make significant adjustments to theirdaily operati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> greater the exposure to risk that a bankinginstituti<strong>on</strong> assumes due to lack of credible documentati<strong>on</strong>or an unreliable legal framework, themore it needs to charge higher interest rates andguarantees to loan ratio requirements. Thus, inmany developing countries, bank loan portfoliosare often over-collateralised (guarantees to loanratios of greater than <strong>on</strong>e), which further limitscredit access. In H<strong>on</strong>duras, creditors ask <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> aguarantee of 150 percent of the value of a loan.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> low access to credit in the developing worldalso relates to limited competiti<strong>on</strong> in the financialservices industries of many countries and thestate’s impositi<strong>on</strong> of high licensing requirements<strong>on</strong> financial intermediaries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are also fundamentalproblems of scale in lending that do notfavour those with meagre assets.Innovative lending schemes such as the grouplendingschemes pi<strong>on</strong>eered by the Grameen Bank,BRAC 63 in Bangladesh, and NGOs in some othercountries, have been able to somewhat circumventthe problem of limited access of the poor tocollateral. By tying each group member’s abilityto receive loans to the repayment of other members(i.e., <strong>on</strong>e member’s failure to make a loanpayment results in the loss of credit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the othermembers), loans are essentially secured by peerpressure. However, such lending schemes shouldnot be c<strong>on</strong>sidered a replacement <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>alcredit providers, as their small lending portfolios,often prohibitively high interest rates, and reliance<strong>on</strong> external funding limit the potential reach.Costs of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> barriers discussed above clearly establishthe reas<strong>on</strong>s why the poor opt to remain inin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises oftenhave limited access to broader ec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunitiesand are especially vulnerable to the uncertainties,the corrupti<strong>on</strong> and even violence prevalentoutside the rule of law and have few meansto settle disputes apart from bribery or violence.Without legal rights or protecti<strong>on</strong>, they are in ac<strong>on</strong>tinual state of legal and political vulnerability.Small in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses assume larger risks(than the larger and usually <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal firms) andspend more time and resources to m<strong>on</strong>itor theiragents and partners (which explains why theyusually hire relatives and close friends). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ychoose low-risk businesses that often yield lowreturns. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y operate with a limited amount ofcapital and as a result, they are <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced to dobusiness at a very small scale. Since they hardlyaccumulate capital, it is very difficult to leaveor sell the business to pass <strong>on</strong> benefits of bothtangible and intangible assets. 64<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> relati<strong>on</strong>ship between poverty, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality andpolitical alienati<strong>on</strong> leaves the poor especially vulnerableto organised crime and other unscrupulousparties that rise up to fill the gaps. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malitymore accessible could legally empower the poorto grow their businesses, enjoy the appreciati<strong>on</strong> oftheir assets in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal property markets, and accesscredit more easily. This is the visi<strong>on</strong> of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>as a means to alleviate poverty. 65<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> benefits that a business pers<strong>on</strong> would obtainby going into the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, would be thatregistrati<strong>on</strong> of ownership rights in property wouldmean having capital to collateralise; there couldbe state support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> collecti<strong>on</strong> of obligati<strong>on</strong>s;greater ease and record of transacti<strong>on</strong>s and hopefully,increased protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> intellectual property227


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chart below captures broadly the costs and benefits to businesses of being <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal versus in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal.INFORMALITYCostsFewer mechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> dealing with risk and uncertaintyBribe and Corrupti<strong>on</strong>Lack of identityLimited access to ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale and scope (markets are limited to family circles)Impossibility of diversifying risks and investmentsHigher transport costsRisk of losing family assets, unlimited liabilityLess access to market knowledgeDiffi culty to establish business hierarchies different from the family <strong>on</strong>esDiffi culty to divide and specialize labourEn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing c<strong>on</strong>tracts <strong>on</strong>ly by <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceLimited Access to capitalShort-term fi rms and investmentLosing the advantages of advertising because they have to hide their businessUnpredictability (inspecti<strong>on</strong>s, laws, etc)Higher credit costsBenefitsAvoiding the costs of<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality (taxes, permits,regulati<strong>on</strong>s)FORMALITYCostsAdministrative PermitsTaxesProduct Regulati<strong>on</strong>sLabour Regulati<strong>on</strong>s228BenefitsLimited LiabilityShielding the fi rms from shareholders & creditorsEn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable rules and agreements am<strong>on</strong>g partners Predictable rules to withdraw capitalfrom the fi rm<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> possibility of issuing shares that facilitate the perpetual successi<strong>on</strong> of the firm, canbe used to raise capital, transmit info about the business and represent rights over theenterpriseAccess to business identificati<strong>on</strong> mechanisms that transmit in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about the nati<strong>on</strong>alidentity, address, the assets they own, their financial history, etc.Access to rules that establish en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable standards of resp<strong>on</strong>sibility am<strong>on</strong>g partners,administrators and workers, allowing a more efficient divisi<strong>on</strong> and specializati<strong>on</strong> of labourand achieving ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scaleEn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable c<strong>on</strong>tracts, Access to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal c<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms<strong>Legal</strong>ly advertise and protecti<strong>on</strong> of brands and trademarksPredictable and speedy rules <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> closing of business,Default rulesMembership of trade associati<strong>on</strong>sPermits to use public land, resources and utilities.Access to incentives packages such as tax rebates, exports licenses and trade fairsFlexibility


ights. Other benefits would include a potentiallylarger market, or at least easier access to largermarkets. Although business pers<strong>on</strong>s in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy routinely trade across borders, inAfrica, <strong>on</strong>ly the people in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal market areable to import or export through major ports or anyother major transit areas, given the presence ofcustoms and other border officials. A benefit of beingin the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal market, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, is the potentialto grow a larger business and to get out of poverty.As discussed in the next secti<strong>on</strong>, this costbenefitanalysis highlights the areas wherethe law can make the transiti<strong>on</strong> from the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malto the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omies easier. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> role <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thelaw, then, is to reduce the costs and enhance thebenefits of entering the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Becausethe process may be l<strong>on</strong>g, and because theexistence of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is an adaptiveresp<strong>on</strong>se rather than moral failure, the law shouldnot seek to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce the poor out of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy by increasing costs or reducing benefits.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> point is to empower the poor to leave thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and to provide incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>them to choose to do so.Rights-based <strong>Legal</strong> EmpowermentMost people enter the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy not bychoice but out of a need to survive. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> decentwork deficits are most pr<strong>on</strong>ounced in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, where the majority of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesseshave little or no social protecti<strong>on</strong> andreceive little or no social security. Poor respect<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>, or lack of freedom of associati<strong>on</strong>, make it difficult<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> workers and employers to organise in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. 66In 2001, an ILO C<strong>on</strong>ference c<strong>on</strong>cluded thatin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality is principally a governance issue and itencouraged employers’ and workers’ organisati<strong>on</strong>sto extend their representati<strong>on</strong> throughout the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> growth of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omycan often be traced to inappropriate, ineffective,misguided or badly implemented macroec<strong>on</strong>omicand social policies, often developed withouttripartite c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s am<strong>on</strong>g workers, employersand governments. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers’ representatives <strong>on</strong> thecommittee <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cefully stressed that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality isnot a soluti<strong>on</strong> to unemployment and the resultingreport called <strong>on</strong> governments to provide c<strong>on</strong>ducivemacroec<strong>on</strong>omic, social, legal and political frameworks<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the large-scale creati<strong>on</strong> of sustainable,decent jobs and business opportunities.However a fundamental c<strong>on</strong>cern in the recogniti<strong>on</strong>of rights is the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual legalidentity, as expressed by M. Woolcock: 67To the extent there is now a broad scholarly andpolicy c<strong>on</strong>sensus <strong>on</strong> the importance of propertyrights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> development — i.e., <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> encouraginginvestment by the poor (and others) insmall business ventures; or, c<strong>on</strong>comitantly, arecogniti<strong>on</strong> that endemic corrupti<strong>on</strong>, costlybureaucratic delays and weak c<strong>on</strong>tract en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementall undermine capacities and incentives tomake such investments — it is also importantto appreciate that resp<strong>on</strong>ding effectively tothese c<strong>on</strong>cerns is not simply (or <strong>on</strong>ly) a matterof encouraging policymakers to ‘grant’ propertyrights, ‘stamp out corrupti<strong>on</strong>’ or make relevantline ministries ‘more efficient.’ In the mostelementary sense, property rights must be givento actual people, who themselves — in order toadvance and defend their pers<strong>on</strong>al status andidentity. A crucial prerequisite, then, to enhancingthe quality of property rights is ensuring thatresidents/citizens have recognised documents(such as birth, death, marriage and divorcecertificates) verifying such basic in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> astheir name, age, sex and marital status.To balance between rights and market-basedapproaches, emphasis should be laid <strong>on</strong> programmesproviding increased wages, governmentassistance, educati<strong>on</strong>, land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, labour m<strong>on</strong>itoring,and access to credit, which are good starts229


in helping the poor create wealth. However, instituti<strong>on</strong>alre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m is needed to eradicate poverty, attaindevelopment, and successfully transiti<strong>on</strong> to freemarket ec<strong>on</strong>omies. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that reduce bureaucraticred tape and bring the cost of legal complianceunder that of extra-legality are necessary to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malise those who were previously excluded.Such re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms should also create greater regulatorytransparency, allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> citizen input, and aim atfighting corrupti<strong>on</strong> and inefficiency. When tailoredto local circumstances, titling programmes thatturn dead assets of the poor into useable capitalare great tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>, development,and attaining legal inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mals. 68To Sum Up<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>straints and barriers discussed in thischapter clearly establish the reas<strong>on</strong>s why the pooropt to remain in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises often have limited access to broaderec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities and are especiallyvulnerable to uncertainties, corrupti<strong>on</strong> and evenviolence which is prevalent outside the rule oflaw. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y have few means to settle disputes apartfrom bribery or violence. Without legal rights orprotecti<strong>on</strong>, they are in a c<strong>on</strong>tinual state of legaland political vulnerability. Thus making <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malitymore accessible could legally empower the poorto grow their businesses, enjoy the appreciati<strong>on</strong>of their assets in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal property markets, andaccess credit more easily. This is the visi<strong>on</strong> of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> as a means to alleviate poverty whichhas been the focus of this as well as the followingsecti<strong>on</strong> which highlights the importance of accessto markets, goods and services and infrastructure.4. Empowering In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEnterprises through accessto markets, goods andservices, and infrastructureImproving the functi<strong>on</strong>ing of markets<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> close correlati<strong>on</strong> between being poor andoperating in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy in the ruraland the urban sectors is c<strong>on</strong>spicuous. Also, highbusiness costs and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy movein parallel in resp<strong>on</strong>se to ill-designed, unstableand n<strong>on</strong>-participatory rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s, lackof secure property rights, inadequate governmentcapacity and resources to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce laws and regulati<strong>on</strong>s,a lack of transparency, accountability andaut<strong>on</strong>omy of judicial process as well as high degreeof macroec<strong>on</strong>omic instability and corrupti<strong>on</strong>.Inadequate access to markets, and poor quality orn<strong>on</strong>-existent basic public services and infrastructurefurther lead to low productivity, particularly<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses.Agriculture accounts <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a large share of grossdomestic product (GDP) and employment inSub-Saharan Africa. It is primarily a family activity,a comp<strong>on</strong>ent of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy with themajority of farmers being small holders owningbetween 0.5 and 2.0 hectares. Women providenearly 50 percent of the labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce and producemost of the food crops <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the family. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> recentreview by the Independent Evaluati<strong>on</strong> Group ofthe World Bank assistance to agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa makes a pressing case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thenecessity of access to credits and markets, roads,fertilisers, seeds, water, etc. by the impoverishedfarmers to sustain their lives and livelihoods.Given that poor households are c<strong>on</strong>centratedin agriculture, any improvement in their livelihoodswould necessitate entail in part in making230


agricultural activities more productive. Improvedaccess to markets and technology are there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eimportant as is the need to strengthen propertyrights and create better methods of risk management.At the same time, well over half of the 1.1 billi<strong>on</strong>people projected to join the world’s populati<strong>on</strong>between now and 2030 may live in under-servicedslums 69 thereby raising the urban populati<strong>on</strong>,including those living in poverty, well abovethat of rural areas. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, c<strong>on</strong>flicts andnatural disasters are causing migrati<strong>on</strong> fromthose areas to developing countries with relativelygreater ec<strong>on</strong>omic strength in order to seekout entrepreneurial and business opportunities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se migrants glide into the burge<strong>on</strong>ing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy of the countries of destinati<strong>on</strong> and inthe absence of inclusive development processes,the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy would c<strong>on</strong>tinue to expand.Of the three billi<strong>on</strong> urban dwellers today, <strong>on</strong>ebilli<strong>on</strong> live in ‘slums’ i.e. in areas where peoplelack access to key necessities such as potablewater, sanitati<strong>on</strong>, basic energy services or durablehousing. 70 For the slum inhabitants, disease andviolence are threats faced <strong>on</strong> a daily basis andhealth care and educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the children are adistant hope. As the pro poor growth re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m mustincrease the utilisati<strong>on</strong> of the marketable assetsof the poor, it is vital to ensure that markets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor are better integrated in to the ec<strong>on</strong>omywith efficient backward and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward linkages.Accordingly, targeted public investments needto be stepped up in educati<strong>on</strong>, healthcare,water and sanitati<strong>on</strong> and energy services, andinfrastructure 71 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> enabling entrepreneurship andgenerating sustainable livelihoods. Also publicinvestments are crucial <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ‘private-basedec<strong>on</strong>omy’ to prosper and to allow the private sectorto create employment and sustain l<strong>on</strong>g termSustainable LivelihoodsFrameworkA livelihood is sustainable if it can recoverfrom stresses and shocks while maintainingor enhancing the necessary capabilities andassets. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> interventi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> engaging theprivate sector would reduce the vulnerabilityof the poor and increase their resiliencethrough investments in enhancing accessto resources, building assets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> them, andimproving their skills and capabilities tosupport livelihood opportunities and designa living. Income generati<strong>on</strong> is the foundati<strong>on</strong>of a sustainable livelihood. Access to basicservices like energy, water and sanitati<strong>on</strong>,housing and healthcare is fundamental to enablepeople to seek, maintain and c<strong>on</strong>tinueto work. For a livelihood to be sustainable,it must lead to a surplus bey<strong>on</strong>d immediatec<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> requirements to allow additi<strong>on</strong>alresources <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> overcoming shocks andstresses, when required.ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. In the absence of adequateinfrastructure, health services, educati<strong>on</strong>, inclusivefinancial services, etc., market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces al<strong>on</strong>ecan accomplish little.However, these basic and necessary services represent‘missing markets’ or ‘incomplete markets.’While the demand clearly exists, it is not communicatedthrough c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al market characteristicelements because of asymmetric in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>and regulatory and transacti<strong>on</strong> barriers to marketaccess and market creati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> new productsand services. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se, in turn limit the supply ofthese goods and services. Additi<strong>on</strong>al supply-sidec<strong>on</strong>straints include the reluctance of the privatesector to invest in measuring the demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> newproducts and services because of new and rela-231


tively unknown markets that require innovativemarketing mechanisms including multi-stakeholderpartnerships.Increasing Access to Goods andServicesMarkets have to be created to target the groupsthat are currently excluded from them. Forinstance, well focused and participatory policiescan lead to the evoluti<strong>on</strong> of markets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> goodsand services through improvements in producti<strong>on</strong>,distributi<strong>on</strong> and storage comp<strong>on</strong>ents of thevalue chain and mitigating the risk of starvati<strong>on</strong>.As discussed earlier, lack of access to potablewater, basic sanitati<strong>on</strong>, energy services, and solidwaste management services adversely affects thelives and livelihoods of poor people directly andhas a devastating impact <strong>on</strong> ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to engagein trade and business. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor pay many timesmore <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> water (of questi<strong>on</strong>able quality) and otheressential services than the rich. 72 While in therich countries, public spending <strong>on</strong> health is nearlyUS$3000 per capita, the poorest countries canaf<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d to devote barely US$10 per capita or soto public health per year. 73 At this level of investment,it is not possible to operate and manage aCase Study:New markets lead to new opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rural in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses— VegCARE, KenyaLess than a year ago, Mutulu was living belowthe poverty line, al<strong>on</strong>g with three-quarters of thepopulati<strong>on</strong> of Makueni district in eastern Kenya.Now, he is <strong>on</strong>e of more than 400 farmers sellingvegetables in supermarkets in the UK suchas Tesco and Sainsbury’s.‘Be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, I cycled 10 km each day to sell myproduce to middle men and they gave me lowprices and sometimes did not even buy myproduce.’ Now Mutulu educates his childrenand is saving m<strong>on</strong>ey thanks to VegCARE — abusiness partnership that has helped over 400farmers gain access to markets and, <strong>on</strong> average,doubled their incomes in six m<strong>on</strong>ths.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir baby corn is sold in Tesco and Sainsbury’sand their aubergines, chillies and okra aredestined <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the tables of the Asian communityin the UK.’When VegCARE came and said thatthey would market our produce <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> us, mostpeople doubted them. I was <strong>on</strong>e of the first inthe Kwa Kyai scheme, which now has over 300farmers who decided to join VegCARE.’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> partnership’s roots are in a project, initiallypiloted by CARE, which showed that if smallholderswere given access to markets they couldand were willing to invest in farming. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> projectwas a success but not commercially viable,so CARE linked up with Vegpro, the third largestvegetable buyer and producer in the regi<strong>on</strong> .Asa result, Vegpro’s supply to the market fromsmallholder farmers increased as their incomesand livelihoods improved.Initially Vegpro bought the produce and did notget involved in producti<strong>on</strong>. CARE pre-financedthe producti<strong>on</strong> and provided technical supportto the farmers. Now a rural enterprise, knownas VegCARE, has been <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med to take over theactivities. It is a new type of partnership, bornout of an aid project that was aimed at helpingfarming communities in the l<strong>on</strong>g term — andgiving them ways of making a sustainable living<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themselves, their families and their communities.Source: CARE Canada, 2007232


primary health system. Similarly, it is estimatedthat achieving the Millennium Development Goals<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> water and sanitati<strong>on</strong> would requires additi<strong>on</strong>alannual funding of US$10 - US$25billi<strong>on</strong>; an estimatedUS$700 billi<strong>on</strong> of investment is required tobring electricity to an additi<strong>on</strong>al 1.4 billi<strong>on</strong> people.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is need across much of this world <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>greater resources to effectively deliver basicservices to the poor. While increased financingis a necessary c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>, it is not sufficient toensure that the unmet needs of the poor and thevulnerable are fulfilled. In the case of educati<strong>on</strong>and health services, less<strong>on</strong>s learnt from a numberof developing countries have shown that increaseof funding in any given sector does not alwayslead to delivery of enhanced access and improvedquality of service. Increasing public expendituresmay not lead to anticipated outcomes if the instituti<strong>on</strong>sand professi<strong>on</strong>als resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> deliveryof integrated services have inadequate capacityand are not accountable. Accordingly, capacitydevelopment, participati<strong>on</strong>, transparency and accountabilityare mandatory to ensuring that fundsallocated to public service <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> equitable developmentreach their intended targets.Investments in health, educati<strong>on</strong> and basic services,like energy, water and sanitati<strong>on</strong>, involveincreasingly both the public and private sectors.In many countries, such services are in part beingdelivered through private initiatives that includecooperatives, communities and independentnetwork providers. This in turn has given rise toexperimentati<strong>on</strong> with privatisati<strong>on</strong> of core functi<strong>on</strong>sof the state (services delivery, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example)and increasing participati<strong>on</strong> of delivery throughoperators in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Privatisati<strong>on</strong>has not yielded many positive results as itreduces the ability of the state to define an activesocial and ec<strong>on</strong>omic agenda. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operatorsrequire regulati<strong>on</strong> as well as capacity development,particularly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the perspective of qualityc<strong>on</strong>trol and also <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sumer protecti<strong>on</strong>.But, since the poor interact with the privatesector, both as c<strong>on</strong>sumers and entrepreneurs,the private sector can play an important role indelivering goods and services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> developmentand poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong>. This would work best inpartnerships that also include civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s,because they are vital in assuring theparticipatory and accountable approaches needed<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improving the quality of life of the poor.At the same time, governments are increasinglyrecognising the benefits of decentralisati<strong>on</strong> inmaking the delivery of services more effective.For local communities to take advantage of thebenefits of decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, it is critical to putinstituti<strong>on</strong>s in place <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing accountability,reducing costs of varying kinds (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> transacti<strong>on</strong>s,negotiati<strong>on</strong>s and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of c<strong>on</strong>tracts), and<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> developing adequate capacity to facilitatecoordinati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g public agencies, private enterprises,NGOs, and civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s.Multi-stakeholder partnerships in public servicedelivery involving state and n<strong>on</strong>-state actors canc<strong>on</strong>tribute to mobilising their competitive advantagein terms of capacity and resources from variouspartners and supplementing traditi<strong>on</strong>al directpublic delivery of services.Well-trained and motivated service providers,whether from public, private, or civil societycommunities, and adequate instituti<strong>on</strong>s withtransparent procedures and resp<strong>on</strong>sive accountabilitysystems, are important c<strong>on</strong>stituents ofeffective public service delivery. Involvement ofthe poor themselves in setting service deliverypriorities, infrastructure investment planning,level of service and oversight, resp<strong>on</strong>sive feedbackmechanisms, and accountability, is criticalin determining the quality of service provided.233


Case Study:Linking Markets: Promoting sustainable tourism development with indigenousand rural communities in Latin AmericaAiming at supporting grass-roots initiatives andsmall and community based enterprises c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong>in the tourism sector, the ILO has beensupporting a programme in Latin America, themain purpose of which is to assist rural andindigenous communities usually engaged inwork in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, to gain greateraccess to new markets and business developmentservices.Operating since 2000, REDTURS is nowpresent in seven Latin American countries; itrelies <strong>on</strong> a network of communities, instituti<strong>on</strong>s,and resources devoted to encouraging thedevelopment of sustainable tourism keeping inmind ec<strong>on</strong>omic productivity, social equity andcultural identity. REDTURS has encouraged thecompetitive advantages of these communitiesin fostering quality job creati<strong>on</strong> and productivityincreases mainly through three strategies: a)improving the service supplied by making themost out of existing social capital and trainingthe community’s labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce; b) gaining marketshares by applying a five-point marketing strategy;and c) establishing strategic cooperativealliances involving other networks and internati<strong>on</strong>alagencies. By promoting participatorymechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> dialogue and capacity building<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> local partners, REDTURS supported thecreati<strong>on</strong> of four nati<strong>on</strong>al community tourismnetworks that have benefited several indigenouscommunities. Source: ILO<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> provisi<strong>on</strong> of efficient, reliable and af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dablepublic infrastructure services should work as acatalytic incentive encouraging enterprises inthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy to move upwards al<strong>on</strong>g thec<strong>on</strong>tinuum towards greater <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>.Inclusive financial servicesLimited access to working capital and financialservices including risk management services isresp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> holding back the growth potentialof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises. Micro-entrepreneurs inthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy regard the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> financeas a top priority. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO’s Global Agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Employment identifies the c<strong>on</strong>straints <strong>on</strong> thedevelopment and growth of efficient and competitiveenterprises as ‘a wide swath of policy areasparticularly those arising from difficult accessto credit and other financial markets.’ 74 Financecan be a dominant tool to initiate and rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceself organisati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g those in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. It is often the m<strong>on</strong>etary transacti<strong>on</strong>sthat catalyse the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> of joint liability andsolidarity groups, some of which develop multipurposeself-help organisati<strong>on</strong>s.Access to finance is essential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> creating anenterprise and keeping it going. A c<strong>on</strong>siderableexpansi<strong>on</strong> of rural bank branches in India promotedn<strong>on</strong>-agricultural output and enhanced ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, the expansi<strong>on</strong> of bankbranches led, indirectly, to an increase in agriculturalwages and reducti<strong>on</strong> of rural poverty. 75But, it is often the case that access to credit inc<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> with macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policies relatingto trade, may work to further strengthenthe larger enterprises while preventing smaller<strong>on</strong>es from gaining access to global markets. Forinstance, export promoti<strong>on</strong> policies favouring thecoir industry in Sri Lanka directed a shift in thesupply of coc<strong>on</strong>ut husks to mechanised units234


(owned by men with access to credit), and awayfrom manual units owned by women who hadlittle access to credit. 76While the availability of credit is a c<strong>on</strong>cern, what isequally important are the terms <strong>on</strong> which it is availableand whether they are within the reach of theexisting and potential entrepreneurs. Most micro,small and medium enterprises need small loansand small-scale deals that banks, in general, areeither unable or sometimes unwilling to provide.At the same time, self-employed workers in thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector do not have collateral to offer as aguarantee. Most operators in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omythere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e look to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal financial sources.Micro-finance‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor are bankable’ is the important less<strong>on</strong>we have learnt after nearly three decades ofCase Study:Alternate Model of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Credit: SMEs Helping In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises in PeruVincent Sanchez lives in the community ofSan Martin de Porres, with his wife, Ruth, andtheir two kids. This is a semi-<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlement,where an associati<strong>on</strong>, rather than the city ofLima, provides electricity and water. Vincent has15-years experience in the metal working businessand lives in San Martin de Porres whichmeans he is not able to qualify <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a loan fromthe bank. As part of a credit programme operatedby the medium-sized enterprise, Promac,he was recently able to purchase a large metalworking machine (valued at approximatelyUS$5000). Vincent and his wife, who is also amicro-entrepreneur, now make enough m<strong>on</strong>eyto support their family, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their kids to attendschool, and to pay off the loan <strong>on</strong> the machine.Be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e negotiating the loan <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the machine,Vincent commuted an hour and a half each wayto work. Now, he <strong>on</strong>ly travels <strong>on</strong>ce a week tothe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal market to sell the metal pieces hemakes, and market demand is now outpacinghis producti<strong>on</strong> capacity. Vincent does not have atax number, and he pays no taxes to the federalor local government.Approximately 15 percent of Promac’s clientshave a private loan arrangement, similar to the<strong>on</strong>e Vincent has. Segundo, Promac’s founder,says that a typical growth path <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a businesslike Vincent’s would be to outgrow his homebasedoperati<strong>on</strong> within two to three years, andto move into the industrial z<strong>on</strong>e of the city. Bythis time, Vincent should be able to engage witha few larger clients who would no doubt insist<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal tax receipts, eventually warranting theexpense of registering the business. Once hemoves into the industrial area, Vincent says hewill register the business with the appropriatelocal municipal agencies to avoid some of thecurrent hassles and to access larger loans fromthe banks. Hassles include intermittent electricityloss within San Martin de Porras, which hasthe potential to affect Vincent’s ability to re-payhis loan <strong>on</strong> time. In urban areas, 95 percent ofhouseholds have electricity, however this dropsto just 86 percent in the lowest ec<strong>on</strong>omic quintile(Sociometro, 2007).Promac has a loan repayment rate of 100percent. Some clients are late with their payments<strong>on</strong> occasi<strong>on</strong>, but the company also offersa work-repayment opti<strong>on</strong>, where clients work inthe Promac factory <strong>on</strong> an hourly basis as a wayof paying off the loan. Promac credits its successto a hands-<strong>on</strong> approach and a keen senseof the potential in its clientele.235


micro-finance activities. Micro-finance plays apivotal role in providing sustainable livelihoods bystimulating small businesses. Although microfinance77 is becoming increasingly available tomicro-entrepreneurs, frequently their <strong>on</strong>ly opti<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> access to capital are through in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal financialarrangements with priced transacti<strong>on</strong>s, rotatingsavings and credit associati<strong>on</strong>s (ROSCAs),or m<strong>on</strong>eylenders who usually provide emergencyloans, often <strong>on</strong> usurious terms. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> latter may notbe able to lend as per the needs of the growingenterprises. Furthermore, despite the positiveresp<strong>on</strong>se to the progress of micro-finance, therehas so far been little involvement by the world’slargest financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s in micro-financesuccesses. To be sure, there are currently examplesof large private sector banks entering intorisk-sharing partnerships with NGO micro-financeinstituti<strong>on</strong>s that merge the social mobilisati<strong>on</strong>skills and rural presence of NGOs with the capitalresources and financial credibility of the bank.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts, however, need to be leveraged toenhance access to financial resources by microand small enterprises. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> comm<strong>on</strong>ality betweenin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal finance and micro-finance is in that theyc<strong>on</strong>sider the households and the enterprise as aunit and are usually not c<strong>on</strong>cerned with how theloan is used — whether <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, productiveinvestment or saving.Related to the issue of exploring the integrati<strong>on</strong>of micro-finance with the financial sector andthe roles of the private and public sectors, it isimportant to analyse the impact of policies 78 thatwill encourage greater financial sector involvementwith the markets and with demand by the poorand the disadvantaged. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> micro-finance instituti<strong>on</strong>shave induced more competiti<strong>on</strong> in the creditmarket and there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e lowered the credit interestrate that poor people have to pay. Currently theseinstituti<strong>on</strong>s are unable to meet requests <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sumsneeded to take micro-enterprises to a larger scale.SavingsIt is now widely recognised that the poor havea high propensity to save and that there is ac<strong>on</strong>siderable demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> savings instruments andinstituti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> creati<strong>on</strong> over time of smootherflows of income can work to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the basis of an<strong>on</strong>-c<strong>on</strong>tractual insurance against natural, socialand physical shocks and stresses. In West Africa,in most savings-based micro-finance instituti<strong>on</strong>s(credit uni<strong>on</strong>s, village banks or savings, andcredit cooperatives), nearly six times as manypeople make deposits as take out loans at anypoint in time. 79Micro-insuranceEven though there are important links betweenmicro-finance and micro-insurance, a related‘mantra’ that the poor are uninsurable still persists.Increasingly micro-insurance is a part of thedeveloping micro-finance systems.Most entrepreneurs in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,particularly micro and small entrepreneurs, d<strong>on</strong>ot have access to risk management and safetynetmechanism tools that large private firmsdo. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se tools include a range of savings andinsurance products as well as more sophisticatedproducts that minimise risks from macroec<strong>on</strong>omicvariability, such as inflati<strong>on</strong>, as well as shockand stresses from natural hazards and disasters.However, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal mechanisms such as savingsand other traditi<strong>on</strong>al risk management structures,80 have proven very expensive and there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eunsustainable as l<strong>on</strong>g-term coping strategies. 81Access to insurance by the poor reduces thevulnerability of households and increases theirability to take advantage of opportunities. Eventhough micro-insurance is a nascent market, it236


provides protecti<strong>on</strong> to low-income people againstspecific risks and hazards in exchange <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> premiumpayments proporti<strong>on</strong>ate to the likelihoodand costs of the risks involved. 82 By reducing theimpact of household losses that could exacerbatethe poverty situati<strong>on</strong> of households, micro-insurancecan enhance their stability and profitability.However, these insurance instruments are notwidely available <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> managing risks <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong>swith low incomes. If this kind of insurancecould be delivered cost-effectively through microfinanceinstituti<strong>on</strong>s (MFIs), it could represent aprofitable segment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the insurance industry.While previous attempts to launch such productshave not been entirely successful they have pointedthe way to eventual growth. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re definitely isa need to be filled that would allow the poor toalleviate the ec<strong>on</strong>omic impact of natural disasters.Also, micro-health insurance schemes offerreas<strong>on</strong>able guarantees of loan repayment sincethe insurance would provide <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> adequate medicaltreatment to the borrower in the event of serioushealth problems. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, micro-insurancehas the potential to be used as collateral <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowingadditi<strong>on</strong>al credit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business enterprises.Herein lies an important tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the promoti<strong>on</strong>of equitable growth: enhanced access by thepoor to inclusive and gender-resp<strong>on</strong>sive financialproducts and services (like micro-insurance),supported by policies, social instituti<strong>on</strong>s and newtechnologies that reduce market barriers andtransacti<strong>on</strong> costs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se interventi<strong>on</strong>s togetherwith capacity development at human, instituti<strong>on</strong>aland system-wide levels, show the promiseof reducing vulnerabilities am<strong>on</strong>g the poor byassisting them in creating assets, promotingentrepreneurship, improving service delivery, andstrengthening livelihoods.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> private and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sectors are capable ofproviding micro-insurance products, as they candesign and offer sustainable and l<strong>on</strong>g-term riskreducti<strong>on</strong> strategies that are also profitable. Thisrole is being explored comprehensively, both as abusiness model and as an interventi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> socialprotecti<strong>on</strong>. In the process, it will be important tolearn just how micro-insurance relates to governmentpolicies, role of government, and thepublic sector. For now, it is encouraging that asignificant number of insurers are keen to explorethe low-income market; in time, the viability ofa micro-insurance product will be determined bythe demand and its attractiveness, as well as bythe number of potential clients. Currently, theability to pay and incentives to fill the demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the insurance products are comm<strong>on</strong> barriers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>c<strong>on</strong>sumers and suppliers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is anticipati<strong>on</strong>that these barriers can be overcome, in part, byproviding an operati<strong>on</strong>al linkage between microinsuranceand remittances.RemittancesWhile the search <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a better life and livelihoodsdrive rural-urban migrati<strong>on</strong>, the root causes ofinternati<strong>on</strong>al migrati<strong>on</strong> derive from the majorec<strong>on</strong>omic, demographic, and social disparities aswell as c<strong>on</strong>flicts, climate change and envir<strong>on</strong>mentaldegradati<strong>on</strong> or disasters. Remittances c<strong>on</strong>stitutethe most tangible c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of migrants topoverty alleviati<strong>on</strong>. A better understanding of howremittances are used would in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m public policyand development interventi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> migrati<strong>on</strong> andfinancial services and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> enterprise development,livelihoods strengthening and provisi<strong>on</strong>s of otherbasic services. It is equally important is to ensurethat the m<strong>on</strong>ey reaches rural areas as well asother areas where large populati<strong>on</strong>s are still outsidethe banking system with no access to diversefinancial goods and services that can improvetheir quality of life.237


Remittances — the transfer of funds from<strong>on</strong>e place to another, from urban to ruralareas or by developing country nati<strong>on</strong>als sendingearnings back home — can play an instrumentalrole in providing greater access to resources andto safety- net mechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> entrepreneurs atthe bottom of the pyramid. Remittances c<strong>on</strong>stitutethe sec<strong>on</strong>d largest capital flow to developingcountries. It is less than capital that is investeddirectly by private companies but more thanofficial aid. In 2006 remittances in the developingworld amounted to about US$206 billi<strong>on</strong>. Inmany developing countries, amounts sent homeby migrants supporting family and friends weremany times the value of official government-togovernmentaid flows.If the transacti<strong>on</strong> costs of remittances can bereduced, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal channels will substitute in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maltransfers. 83 Fundamental issues involved in makingthis change range from accessible technology,hours of availability, and efficiency of transacti<strong>on</strong>and regulati<strong>on</strong>s, to the profit margins by the instituti<strong>on</strong>sengaged in the process. 84 While it is expectedthat the technology would play an importantrole in lowering the cost of remittances, newbusiness models and a regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>menthold the key to greater access to the services, andefficiency of the transfer process. Better servicecan provide greater profits by integrating remittancesmore fully into financial services offerings<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> migrants and their families. Although theissues are complex, remittance are important <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>developing countries as the amount can provideaccess to additi<strong>on</strong>al financial resources andultimately to the creati<strong>on</strong> and sustainability oflivelihoods.Case Study:C<strong>on</strong>strumex (Mexico) — HelpingMigrants with RemittancesOverview: C<strong>on</strong>strumex helps thousands ofMexican migrants in the U.S. purchase andbuild homes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themselves and their familiesback in Mexico.C<strong>on</strong>straint: C<strong>on</strong>strumex recognised that itsearlier model of serving low-income clientsin Mexico would not work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> migrants inthe U.S., as the latter approached commercialtransacti<strong>on</strong>s with extreme cauti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>company lacked adequate market researchto determine how best to proceed.Soluti<strong>on</strong>: C<strong>on</strong>strumex partnered with Mexicanc<strong>on</strong>sulates in the U.S. to c<strong>on</strong>duct marketresearch <strong>on</strong> the needs of the migrant populati<strong>on</strong>.Following these surveys, it developed anew ‘cash-to-asset’ transfer service that wasoffered through migrant associati<strong>on</strong>s.Source: UNDP, ‘Growing Inclusive Markets — Business <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Development- Development <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Business.’ June 2007<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are several <strong>on</strong>going initiatives at this timeundertaken by different countries, developmentagencies and instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and the learning isevolving. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> governments of origin and destinati<strong>on</strong>have to work together with multilateralorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, private sector, and diaspora andother stakeholders to create opti<strong>on</strong>s, tools andincentives to maximise the development benefitsof remittances. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se incentives and tools can belinked to the transfers themselves (e.g. throughsavings, credit, micro-insurance and micro-pensi<strong>on</strong>schemes) or focus <strong>on</strong> mobilising savings generatedby remittances towards productive investments(made by the migrant, the recipients or a localentrepreneur). This would buttress streamlinedand gender-resp<strong>on</strong>sive remittance policies andregulati<strong>on</strong>s, and strengthen capacity developmentat human, instituti<strong>on</strong>al and system-wide levels.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se collaborative ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts can also catalyse public238


private-partnerships (PPPs) that can lead to innovativedemand-based products and services <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>meeting the needs of the poor people.To summarize: an enabling envir<strong>on</strong>ment, capacityand instituti<strong>on</strong>s that will enhance access tofinance and safety net mechanisms are critical<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the entrepreneurs at the bottom of thepyramid and require innovative approaches.Remittances can be an attractive business <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>micro-finance instituti<strong>on</strong>s and a valuable additi<strong>on</strong>alfinancial service <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> current and potentialmicro-finance clients. Also, micro-insurance canassist in increasing the demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> micro-financeand potentially take micro-finance activities to alarger scale.Public-Private Partnerships<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy is particularly dynamic anddemands a high level of resp<strong>on</strong>siveness from thestate. Even though globalisati<strong>on</strong> is significantlychanging the traditi<strong>on</strong>al role of the State, the roleof the government must remain central in the developmentchoices. One compelling reas<strong>on</strong> is that‘in most re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming countries the private sectordid not step in to fill the vacuum when the publicsector withdrew.’ 85At the same time, developing countries arerecognising the importance of markets and theyunderstand that markets have to be created andgoverned. And sometimes the private sector hasto be motivated to do what needs to be d<strong>on</strong>ethrough the strengthening of the policy envir<strong>on</strong>ment,and through incentives and removal ofbarriers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> market creati<strong>on</strong>. An efficient privatesector depends <strong>on</strong> a sound domestic macroenvir<strong>on</strong>ment that fosters good trade policies andinstituti<strong>on</strong>al foundati<strong>on</strong>s, and adequate capacityto maximise benefits from the macro globalenvir<strong>on</strong>ment and to promote distributi<strong>on</strong>al equity.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> private sector is keen to harm<strong>on</strong>ise privateinterest with public interest because, inter alia,it has started recognising the potential businessopportunities. Accordingly, the private sector isactively promoting new approaches to alleviatingpoverty, opening opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all c<strong>on</strong>cerned,including the poor people and the private sectorcompanies. While private financial instituti<strong>on</strong>sare willing to develop innovative partnershipmodels to provide access to inclusive financialservices, they need assistance in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulatingappropriate policies and strengthening capacitiesthat would remove barriers to market creati<strong>on</strong>and expansi<strong>on</strong> of market access to entrepreneursat the base of the pyramid. Governments, meanwhile,should be encouraging private financial instituti<strong>on</strong>sto garner savings, l<strong>on</strong>g-term credit andmarket-based social protecti<strong>on</strong> instruments in ruraland underserved areas, 86 hence the emphasis<strong>on</strong> public-private partnerships. Also, partnershipwith the private sector is no l<strong>on</strong>ger simply aboutmobilisati<strong>on</strong> of resources; it is also about acting<strong>on</strong> knowledge gained from the wealth of collectiveexperience about entrepreneurship, managementskills and global networking.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> challenge to make the ‘missing markets’play an ec<strong>on</strong>omic role in job creati<strong>on</strong> andservice delivery lies less in finding technologicalsoluti<strong>on</strong>s to producti<strong>on</strong> and distributi<strong>on</strong> and morein structuring instituti<strong>on</strong>s, capacities, incentivesand regulati<strong>on</strong>s. And, if sustainable, high qualityand af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable basic services are actually to bedelivered to the poor and disadvantaged, capacitiesmust be built to engage the talents and energiesof the greater community and to allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>real and meaningful ownership of the activities ofthe different stakeholders.Public-private partnerships hold great promise inthis endeavour, especially if they were given anenabling envir<strong>on</strong>ment that removed barriers tothe entry by the smaller and community-based239


Case Study:Durban: A Heterogeneous Soluti<strong>on</strong> Through Public Private Partnership<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> city of Durban in South Africa, took an<strong>on</strong>-restrictive approach to street vending. Itdemarcated sites throughout the city; changedthe legal framework that governed street tradingfrom criminal to administrative law; decreasedthe cost of trading spaces; and guaranteed servicessuch as basic shelter, solid waste removal,water, toilets, lighting, and storage facilities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> city also created an appeal committee offive members, of whom at least <strong>on</strong>e was requiredto be a street vendor, where municipaldecisi<strong>on</strong>s can be reviewed.However, as the majority of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesseswere in the traditi<strong>on</strong>al medicine sector, it wasnecessary to provide access to market. Over30,000 people, mostly women, worked in thissector. Through direct interventi<strong>on</strong>, Durbanbuilt a dedicated market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> traditi<strong>on</strong>al medicinetraders with shelter, storage, water, andtoilet facilities. It also trained gatherers <strong>on</strong> cultivatingproducts and sustainable harvest techniquesand is currently planning to establisha company to procure materials from growers,process them in partnership with a pharmaceuticalfirm, and market the products.(Source: Lund and Skinner, 2005.)Case Study:Buy-back Centres <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waste Collectors:A Public-Private-Community Partnership ModelWaste collectors are am<strong>on</strong>gst the poorest ofthose working in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. In SouthAfrica, since legislated racial segregati<strong>on</strong> ofurban areas was abolished, there have beenincreasing numbers of waste collectors operatingthroughout its cities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are largely blackwomen whose incomes are extremely low. In themid-1990s the Self Employed Women’s Uni<strong>on</strong>(SEWU) organised cardboard collectors in theinner city of Durban/<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>kwini. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> uni<strong>on</strong> foundthat these collectors were innumerate and oftenexploited by unscrupulous middle-men, and itlobbied local government to assist them.Through SEWU’s activism, and the understandingby the City Council that waste collecti<strong>on</strong>provided a livelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> many residents, a buybackcentre was established in the inner city.This is a public-private-community partnership.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Council provided a small plot of centrallylocatedland that was c<strong>on</strong>verted into the centre,and a large private-sector recycler provided thescales, storage c<strong>on</strong>tainers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cardboard andtrolleys <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the collectors. SEWU worked al<strong>on</strong>gsidecity officials to design the interventi<strong>on</strong>and trained the cardboard collectors <strong>on</strong> how toweight their cardboard. Through this interventi<strong>on</strong>,the collectors sold their cardboard directlyto the recycling company. This has substantiallyincreased the (albeit still low) incomes of thesewaste collectors. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> success of the inner citybuy-back centre has led to the Council establishinga number of similar centres throughoutthe city. (Source: Mgingqizana, 2002.)240


enterprises. Developing effective skills <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> nurturingpartnerships, en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing transparent rule of law(including efficient c<strong>on</strong>tracting and procurementprocesses), and improving managerial capabilitycould go a l<strong>on</strong>g way to encourage the creati<strong>on</strong>and then to sustain such PPPs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir energiescould be tapped to meet the needs of the poor <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>basic services. For instance, it is estimated thatthe achievement of the MDG goals <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> water andsanitati<strong>on</strong> will require enormous annual budgetaryoutlays. A very different and more manageablescenario is <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eseen if ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to achievethese targets were supplemented by servicedelivery through PPPs, particularly if the localcommunities were empowered to manage theirneeds through effective value-chain strategies. Ifeffectively <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulated, PPPs would generate benefitsbey<strong>on</strong>d the obvious <strong>on</strong>es of providing jobsand livelihoods. Health in the communities couldbe improved and children could have greater opportunitiesto attend schools.Ec<strong>on</strong>omic success requires getting the balanceright between the government and the market interms of who should provide the goods and servicesand how they should be provided. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> balanceis, of course, country-specific and depends<strong>on</strong> the level of development. While recognisingthe critical role of governments in creating foundati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a healthy and dynamic private sector,it is vital to develop innovative models of PPPsboth at the local levels as well as nati<strong>on</strong>al levels,to harness resources, capacity and skills of theprivate sector to benefit nati<strong>on</strong>al development. 87influences all development activities. At the sametime, assurance is needed that the supportingstate and public policies are functi<strong>on</strong>ing, that thenecessary regulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> creating greater equity isin place, and above all — that the arrangementworks.To Sum Up<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> discussi<strong>on</strong> in this secti<strong>on</strong> has focussed <strong>on</strong>sound ec<strong>on</strong>omic governance that provides policies,laws, regulati<strong>on</strong>s, instituti<strong>on</strong>s, practices,and individuals to support a strategic partnershipof government, private sector and civil society <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>delivery of basic goods and services and accessto markets. In additi<strong>on</strong>, issues were explored c<strong>on</strong>cerningaccess to finance and safety net mechanismswhich are critical <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs,particularly micro-finance, micro-insuranceand the matter of remittances and savings am<strong>on</strong>gvarious other financial services and portfolios.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> next secti<strong>on</strong> focuses <strong>on</strong> soluti<strong>on</strong>s that authoritiesand businesses (i.e., bottom-up and viceversa) have developed based <strong>on</strong> real life problemsand experiences. Experiences and soluti<strong>on</strong>s comefrom all aspects of business life and several differentcountries. An advantage of evidence-basedsoluti<strong>on</strong>s is that measures successfully adoptedby <strong>on</strong>e country may be replicated in others, withnecessary modificati<strong>on</strong>s.Successful mobilisati<strong>on</strong> of the communities,whether through the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts of the government,the private sector or NGOs, represents collectiveacti<strong>on</strong> at the local level. Though the interventi<strong>on</strong>sinvolved in working <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> new ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth outcomes reflect local interventi<strong>on</strong>s, theirimplementati<strong>on</strong> recognises a global c<strong>on</strong>text that241


5. Instituti<strong>on</strong>al changesand legal toolsmaking a difference <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises —an evidence-based approachIn the earlier secti<strong>on</strong>s of this chapter, we referredto c<strong>on</strong>straints and barriers businesses have facedin their operati<strong>on</strong>s, as well as the need to broadenaccess to markets, services and infrastructure.We now focus <strong>on</strong> soluti<strong>on</strong>s that authorities andbusinesses have developed based <strong>on</strong> real-lifesituati<strong>on</strong>s, problems, and experiences. Experiencescome from a number of countries and fromall aspects of business life.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main advantage of evidence-based soluti<strong>on</strong>sis that measures successfully adopted by<strong>on</strong>e country can — with necessary modificati<strong>on</strong>s— be replicated in others. Instead of academicdiscussi<strong>on</strong>s, realities exist <strong>on</strong> the ground and canbe borrowed and implemented.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mat we adopt <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> evidence-based soluti<strong>on</strong>sare the same — from business start-up tobusiness exit — as described in our discussi<strong>on</strong> ofbarriers and c<strong>on</strong>straints to keep c<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mity andmaintain the linkage. We also present cases ofre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that have taken place both from theperspectives of the top (due to sustained pressuresfrom the bottom) as well as initiativesundertaken at the local/grass-root level or by theprivate sector.Improvement in the quality of instituti<strong>on</strong>s in anec<strong>on</strong>omy has to proceed simultaneously with trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>of the nature and efficiency of its in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. Learning from the instituti<strong>on</strong>-buildingexperience of the industrialised countries, andthose in transiti<strong>on</strong>, as well as from other developingcountries, can be valuable. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are severalgood practice examples from around the world toillustrate how c<strong>on</strong>straints of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesseshave been successfully addressed through instituti<strong>on</strong>aland policy changes. At the same time, nati<strong>on</strong>aland local-level instituti<strong>on</strong>al changes can beinitiated implicitly by introducing new ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivities to provide direct and measurable benefitsto those who will be influenced by the instituti<strong>on</strong>alchange. Ability of the populati<strong>on</strong> impacted bythe instituti<strong>on</strong>al change to recognise the tangiblebenefits provides ownership. And, the ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivity becomes an agent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and a catalyst of,derived demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> appropriate instituti<strong>on</strong>s. 89 Forinstance, ec<strong>on</strong>omic empowerment based <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivity is a step towards gender equality, 90even though these are not syn<strong>on</strong>ymous with it.Linking creative ec<strong>on</strong>omic activities with businessrights in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy has an addedadvantage in that it allows <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a learning-by-doingapproach to implementing instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.It also allows a synergistic linkage betweenre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms from above, including those initiated bygovernments or promoted by internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>swith effective acti<strong>on</strong> from below — <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, by civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s and theorganisati<strong>on</strong>s of the poor themselves.<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment entails making laws andregulati<strong>on</strong>s appropriate and relevant to the realitiesof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses. Some successfulinnovati<strong>on</strong>s are discussed below. It also requiresa just and fair system of en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of laws.Specifically, it implies:• A competent, independent judiciary, applyingthe law equally and evenly <strong>on</strong> all members ofthe community. Essential are educati<strong>on</strong> of thelegal professi<strong>on</strong>, full publicati<strong>on</strong> and disseminati<strong>on</strong>of legal texts including judicial decisi<strong>on</strong>s;• Transparent, coherent laws, including laws <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>242


Case Study:‘Tell us how to make legal mechanisms and tools work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses.’ President Benjamin Mkapa, TanzaniaIn 2005 President Benjamin Mkapa of Tanzaniaproposed that the next government should speedup the process of bringing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesseswithin the legal ambit to shore up achievementsrecorded and spur further the country’s ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> president made the remarks whenhe launched a report <strong>on</strong> the Diagnosis Phase ofthe Property and Business Formalisati<strong>on</strong> Programme<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tanzania. Quoting the 2005 GlobalCompetitive Report released by the World Ec<strong>on</strong>omicForum, Mkapa noted that Tanzania hadclimbed 11 places above last year’s rating andovertaken Uganda and Kenya partly because ofthe c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> by in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses. In orderto take Tanzania to the next level of development,the President specifically sought answersto the following:a) How are we going to turn all this recogniti<strong>on</strong>into something accessible and beneficial tothe 98 per cent of business operating outsidethe legal system?b) How can we enable people to leverage theirparticipati<strong>on</strong> in this competitive envir<strong>on</strong>mentwhen probably 89 percent of their assets areheld in the extra-legal sector?c) What legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms should be instituted torecognise, protect and ’<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malise’ of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maloperators’ assets?d) What needs to be d<strong>on</strong>e to ensure our peoplebenefit from the growing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and marketec<strong>on</strong>omy?e) Due to lack of recogniti<strong>on</strong> legally, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malentrepreneurs have created their own mechanismsof documentati<strong>on</strong>, registrati<strong>on</strong>, fungibilityand collateral, and testament.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs have developed archetypesof business organisati<strong>on</strong>s and expandedmarkets outside the legal sector,’ he added.‘How can we bring these organisati<strong>on</strong>s into themainstream and provide recogniti<strong>on</strong>? And thereal challenge is to use these archetypes as abasis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a new system wherein people can relateto and access, and thus bring down the barriersthat stifle entrepreneurship. How to remove thosebarriers that exclude them from participating inthe markets we seek to create, and that retardour poverty-reducti<strong>on</strong> ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts. Mkapa said Tanzaniac<strong>on</strong>tinues to be excluded from the benefits ofan expanded market ec<strong>on</strong>omy, and it was time tobring them in. He called <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> support from stakeholdersand development partners, n<strong>on</strong>-governmentalorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s ,andothers in the protecti<strong>on</strong> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of thehard-w<strong>on</strong> assets and business of the majority ofpoor Tanzanians. Source: Guardian, 2005-10-06the protecti<strong>on</strong> and facilitati<strong>on</strong> of business;• Freedom of the press, and adequately paidjournalists to shelter them from bribery;• En<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement officers who apply the law uni<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mlyto all;• Ease of entry into <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal business so that variousbusiness <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms are quickly and cheaply<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med, some to limit the owners’ liability totheir investment in the business;• Significant ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t to reduce grand corrupti<strong>on</strong>and, ultimately, to rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce social norms thatc<strong>on</strong>strain petty corrupti<strong>on</strong>.Of the emerging business laws in some Africancountries, 91 are an example of an important243


step toward this kind of structure. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y do not,however, fully protect transacti<strong>on</strong>s from distorti<strong>on</strong>swithin the nati<strong>on</strong>al judicial systems, andthey have not yet generated the transparencythey are designed to provide as neither the decisi<strong>on</strong>snor the filings have yet been systematicallycomputerized. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> laws also do not address whoc<strong>on</strong>trols the military. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y do, however, create avocabulary and a virtual <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> discussi<strong>on</strong> oflegal predictability and, generally, of the rule oflaw; in this way the laws have facilitated discussi<strong>on</strong>sam<strong>on</strong>g actors in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,including business people as well as lawyers,academics and judges. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> same vocabularyand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um allow social norms underlying <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallaws to influence the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, too, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example when business people with <strong>on</strong>e foot ineach ec<strong>on</strong>omy are vectors <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> transfer of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> appearance in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy ofrelati<strong>on</strong>ships and documents mimicking those inthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy suggests the power of suchtransfers from the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Innovati<strong>on</strong>s which Dem<strong>on</strong>strateBusiness Rights and <strong>Legal</strong>EmpowermentWhile business regulati<strong>on</strong>s vary from country tocountry, and from municipality to municipality,they usually include most of the features bulletedbelow. Resp<strong>on</strong>ses to the obligati<strong>on</strong>s thatfollow from such regulati<strong>on</strong>s are appropriate tothe circumstances of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneursand may be termed ‘empowering’. Most countrieswould expect the following from a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally recognisedbusiness:• Incorporati<strong>on</strong> of the business as a legalentity.• Inclusi<strong>on</strong> in a business registry at the nati<strong>on</strong>al,regi<strong>on</strong>al, or municipal level.• Registrati<strong>on</strong> with the nati<strong>on</strong>al tax authority.• Registrati<strong>on</strong> of employees in pensi<strong>on</strong>/health/other nati<strong>on</strong>al social security schemes.• Acquisiti<strong>on</strong> of building permits, at the municipallevel.• Acquisiti<strong>on</strong> of operating and other licenses,at the municipal level.• Approval of health officials up<strong>on</strong> inspecti<strong>on</strong>(especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sales of food), at the nati<strong>on</strong>aland/or municipal levels.• Safety approval from local fire officials.Starting a BusinessSome of the best practices 92 adopted across theworld to simplify business start-up <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malitiesand registrati<strong>on</strong> are as follows:1. Diagnose the problem:Australia: A task<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce was created to measure theadministrative burden, resulting in the establishmentof a Business License In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> Systems(BLIS) as a <strong>on</strong>e-stop-shop service designed to deliverpertinent governmental in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> to smallbusinesses regarding licenses, applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msand c<strong>on</strong>tact details. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results of BLIS are veryimpressive. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y have reduced the administrativeburden <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business by reducing the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>search cost incurred in trying to establish theirregulatory compliance obligati<strong>on</strong>s. Furthermore,15,000 people use this system every year; and inthe nine m<strong>on</strong>ths between September 1999 andMay 1999, BLIS generated more than 13,500fact sheets and reports <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> new and existing businessvia the Internet al<strong>on</strong>e.Mexico: a special deregulati<strong>on</strong> unit was set upunder the Ministry of Industry and Commerce toreview all existing business <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malities, includingstart-up requirements. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> comprehensiveness ofthe approach led to a more fundamental re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mthan if the government had sought fast results.2. Provide adequate training and resources to244


Case Study:Business Registrati<strong>on</strong> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in UgandaIn Uganda, firms must apply <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> annual ‘tradelicenses’, which combine basic registrati<strong>on</strong> oftheir status with other approvals. This processis a major deterrent to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malising businesses.It takes an average of two days to obtain thelicense at an average compliance cost of about20 percent of per capita GDP. Administrati<strong>on</strong>includes cashiers <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fee payments, registrars<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> reviewing paperwork and issuing the license,a site visit by a health and safety inspector, andapproval by the Local Chairman.Little of this is really necessary, except <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> afew firms which pose significant risks to publichealth or security. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> DFID project introduceda simplified trade licensing process in Entebbemunicipality, involving <strong>on</strong>ly provisi<strong>on</strong> of basicin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> by the entrepreneur, payment of afee, and immediate issue of the license document— all in <strong>on</strong>e stop. This re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m was foundto have brought the following benefits:A cheaper & shorter process: compliance costdropped by 75 percent and is now estimated at2 percent of per capita GDP. Average registrati<strong>on</strong>time is now 30 minutes, down from twodays.Better business-government relati<strong>on</strong>s: businessesfeel that the attitude of the registrati<strong>on</strong> staffis much more positive and pro-business.More businesses registered: registrati<strong>on</strong> levelshave improved by 43 percent. In the first year,four times more businesses registered than inthe previous year.More government revenue: total revenue collecti<strong>on</strong>has increased by 40 percent through moreregistrati<strong>on</strong>s. Individual businesses pay less <strong>on</strong>average.Reduced administrative costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> government:Entebbe municipality estimates a 10 percentreducti<strong>on</strong> in administrative costs. Administrativetime ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t by staff is down by 25 percent.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are reduced waiting lines and hassles <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>businesses.Health & safety inspecti<strong>on</strong>s more targeted &prioritized: inspectors can now target their visits<strong>on</strong> high risk businesses.Better knowledge of business profiles/sectors: anew computerized system and improved compliancegives the local authority better in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms were implemented withoutchanges to nati<strong>on</strong>al level legislati<strong>on</strong> whichwould have been very difficult and slow toachieve. Instead, other legal means were foundto make change. In cases such as this, regulatorybarriers to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> can be reducedwithout large-scale legal change, but ratherthrough small incremental change. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Entebbeexperience is now being replicated in other localauthorities in Uganda.licensing authorities:Australia: Training to licensing authorities <strong>on</strong> theuse of new technologies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business registrati<strong>on</strong>,having the greatest positive effect <strong>on</strong> small businessesand micro enterprises, which generally d<strong>on</strong>ot have resources to spend <strong>on</strong> legal assistance.Ceará, Brazil: Technical assistance given to applicants,many of whom are illiterate or semi-illiterate.Government prepares material <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> SMEs,which explain their rights and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities <strong>on</strong>245


key topics in simple and clear language.Eritrea: <strong>Legal</strong> assistance provided to SMEs tomake better use of their rights and instruments.3. Business Help Centres (BHC) - Create singleaccess point <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> entrepreneurs:Turkey: a <strong>on</strong>e-stop registrati<strong>on</strong> launched in June2003 by combining seven procedures into a singlevisit to the company registry. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> time to start abusiness was cut from 38 days to nine. In additi<strong>on</strong>,applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms were unified and shortened, andregistry officers were trained in customer relati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cost fell by a third and the number of registrati<strong>on</strong>sshot up by 18 percent, almost halving thetime to start a business — from 23 days to 13.Portugal: at the Centro de Formalidades deEmpresa all company registrati<strong>on</strong> procedures areper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med in <strong>on</strong>ly three visits.4. Introducti<strong>on</strong> of standardised <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms resulted insignificant reducti<strong>on</strong> in rejecti<strong>on</strong> rates:In the United Kingdom rejecti<strong>on</strong> rates went downby eight percent, in Malaysia by 11 percent andin Costa Rica by 14 percent. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se can cover allbusiness <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms: sole proprietorship, partnership,limited liability, or corporati<strong>on</strong>.5. Electr<strong>on</strong>ic registrati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong>line <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms and registrydata base in Denmark, Italy, UK, and Norway:electr<strong>on</strong>ic registrati<strong>on</strong>, an innovative and efficientprocedure, has become norm.Australia and Canada: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internet can be usedto file business registrati<strong>on</strong>s, which cuts the administrativecost by more than 50 percent.Netherlands: the Ministry of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Affairshas launched a programme of ‘Forms <strong>on</strong> Line.’Forms are unified under this programme. Registrydatabase should be updated c<strong>on</strong>tinually andaccessible by the Internet. A system should bein place <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> real time access to the database byinspectorates and others who need the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>,such as tax, customs, pensi<strong>on</strong>, and socialsecurity authorities.6. Cut the newspaper publicati<strong>on</strong> requirement:Serbia and M<strong>on</strong>tenegro abolished the requirementto publish a notice in the official gazette.Instead, companies announce their <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>the registry’s website.7. Allow businesses to start activities immediatelyafter registrati<strong>on</strong>:Germany and Italy allow companies to beginactivities as so<strong>on</strong> as they file the required in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>(as l<strong>on</strong>g as it does not involve dangerousactivities). This eliminates ex ante barriers tostart-ups.México: the government created the Sistema deApertura Rápida de Empresas (SARE), which reducedthe number of federal <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malities to open alow-risk business <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> individuals (tax registrati<strong>on</strong>)and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business (tax registrati<strong>on</strong> and enterpriseregistrati<strong>on</strong>). Under the SARE system, it takes<strong>on</strong>e working day to comply with federal startup<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> low-risk activities (specifiedin annex to the decree). As of November 2002,more than 226 000 individuals and 1,400 legalentities have received their tax and enterpriseregistrati<strong>on</strong> under this scheme.8. Impose a ‘silence is c<strong>on</strong>sent’ rule:This means that <strong>on</strong>ce the deadline had passed,the business is automatically c<strong>on</strong>sidered registered.This approach, pi<strong>on</strong>eered in Italy, iscurrently en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced in Armenia, Georgia, andMorocco. All four are am<strong>on</strong>g the world’s fastest20 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> registering a business.9. Reduce or scrap the minimum capital requirement<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> private limited liability companies:In Bosnia and Herzegovina the capital requirementhas been reduced by half.In France, the requirement was abolished.246


10. Establish a single business identificati<strong>on</strong>number to expedite and track the processing ofofficial requests:Oreg<strong>on</strong>: the single business identificati<strong>on</strong>number is used when reporting, paying, makingenquiries about employment-related obligati<strong>on</strong>s— such as withholding, unemployment, andtransit taxes — and worker’s compensati<strong>on</strong> assessments.Ireland: brought together tax registrati<strong>on</strong> details<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> income, social security, and value-added taxesunder a single registrati<strong>on</strong> number. This practicehas also been introduced also in other Europeancountries.11. Involve the private sector in registrati<strong>on</strong>:Serbia: the independent agency registers businessthrough a network of service centres strategicallylocated around the country, and through<strong>on</strong>-line and mail registrati<strong>on</strong>.Italy recently eliminated the role of the courtsaltogether and enjoys substantial efficiencies asa result. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> trend in Europe is toward administrativemanagement of registries and away fromlegal process involving courts and notaries.(A recent study 93 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the European <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>found that key drivers of good registrati<strong>on</strong> areimprovements in internal efficiency in public bodiesthrough better management techniques andper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance measures, accountability, and userc<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>, which implies a client-orientati<strong>on</strong>focused <strong>on</strong> business needs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> study found thatreducti<strong>on</strong> in the involvement of court notaries andother legal bodies were associated with substantialefficiency improvements.)12. Licensing Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms — rati<strong>on</strong>alisati<strong>on</strong>:Russia: the new law <strong>on</strong> licenses significantly reducedthe number of activities subject to licensing,reduced the license fee, and extended theterm of validity of a license to at least five years(from three years). After the adopti<strong>on</strong> of the newlaw, the percentage of the enterprises that applied<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> licenses and permits dropped by a third.13. ‘Get out of the Courts.’ Eliminate the need<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> mandatory use of both notaries and judgesfrom registrati<strong>on</strong>:Bosnia-Herzegovina will make registrati<strong>on</strong> anadministrative process, without resorting to thecourts. Also eliminates the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> judges.Italy: registrati<strong>on</strong> was taken out of the courts,saving three m<strong>on</strong>ths.Serbia and M<strong>on</strong>tenegro adopted legislati<strong>on</strong> to dothe same in May 2004. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> benefits are large.Entrepreneurs in countries where registrati<strong>on</strong>requires a judicial process spend 14 more days tostart a business.Operating a Business1. Reduce the number of inspecti<strong>on</strong>s by governmentauthorities with the excepti<strong>on</strong> of those areaswhere regular inspecti<strong>on</strong>s are needed due to thenature of transacti<strong>on</strong>s. Inspecti<strong>on</strong>s, in general,are based <strong>on</strong> ad hoc system in terms of documentrequirements, interpretati<strong>on</strong> of documents,and intenti<strong>on</strong> of inspectors. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y usually lead tobribes and corrupti<strong>on</strong>:Russia: According to a new Inspecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, any<strong>on</strong>e state agency can carry out no more than <strong>on</strong>einspecti<strong>on</strong> of <strong>on</strong>e and the same firm in two years.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number of inspecti<strong>on</strong>s dropped by a third.2. Private inspecti<strong>on</strong>s and certificati<strong>on</strong> —alternatives to administrative regulati<strong>on</strong>:Australia: a model involving private and third-partycertificati<strong>on</strong> of building compliance by competentbuilding professi<strong>on</strong>als has been incorporatedat the nati<strong>on</strong>al level. It involves the developmentof a model of rati<strong>on</strong>al building legislati<strong>on</strong> devel-247


oped as part of a l<strong>on</strong>g-term regulatory harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong>process in this area.Dubai has implemented this system, while Japanand Malaysia have expressed c<strong>on</strong>siderable interest.Finland introduced several types of privateinspecti<strong>on</strong> in 2004, such as <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> foundati<strong>on</strong>, steelworksand electrical work. All Nordic countries aswell as Australia, Canada, Ghana, Kenya, SouthAfrica, Uganda, the United Kingdom and Zambiahave adopted risk-based inspecti<strong>on</strong>s.3. Simplified and transparent taxati<strong>on</strong> system:Uzbekistan: which used to have a complex andfrequently changeable tax system, recently introduceda fixed simplified taxati<strong>on</strong> system <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> SMEs— a great benefit to individual entrepreneurs,micro-firms, and small enterprises. Instead ofvarious nati<strong>on</strong>al and local taxes, they pay either afixed or a unified tax.Russia: the new Taxati<strong>on</strong> System <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> gave firmsincentives to use a simplified tax system. Insteadof VAT, profit, sales, and property taxes, smallenterprises can pay <strong>on</strong>e unified tax. (Accordingto the old 1995 Russia law, SMEs had to pay 10percent of profit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> federal and 20 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> regi<strong>on</strong>albudgets; 3.3 percent of revenue <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> federaland 6.7 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> regi<strong>on</strong>al budgets, if revenuewas below 7.5 milli<strong>on</strong> roubles and employmentbelow 20 people. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> new Russia law requires15 percent of profit or six percent of revenue, ifrevenue is below 11 milli<strong>on</strong> roubles and employmentbelow 100 people.)4. Tax Identificati<strong>on</strong> Numbers:Australia: introduced ID numbers in real estatetransacti<strong>on</strong>s and banking and financial activities.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> aim is to reduce tax evasi<strong>on</strong> and unreportedactivities by employing computerised tax officesand management in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> systems, setting upregi<strong>on</strong>al in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and audit centres and establishinga system to track unpaid taxes.5. Electr<strong>on</strong>ic Tax declarati<strong>on</strong>s:Mexico is using instruments such as electr<strong>on</strong>icfunds transfer submissi<strong>on</strong> of declarati<strong>on</strong>s throughthe Internet instead of paperwork. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> resultsof this practice have been ast<strong>on</strong>ishing: reducedpaper; expanded customer service coverage; itiseasier <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Ministry of Finance to identify theorigins and the destinati<strong>on</strong> of payments; and lesstime spent in tax compliance.Egypt established a Model Tax and CustomsCentre in 2003. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Centre has brought togetherthe three revenue generating departments in <strong>on</strong>ebuilding with <strong>on</strong>e tax and customs file <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> everytax payer. Efficiency in collecti<strong>on</strong> and avoidanceof double taxati<strong>on</strong> were evident in tax with payers’compliance with the new system.6. Establish a flat tax and cut back special exempti<strong>on</strong>sand privileges:Est<strong>on</strong>ia: 1994 re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m replaced a c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>ladensystem with a single flat tax offering noexempti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> country’s tax base broadened,and revenues have not suffered.Slovakia: in 2003 streamlined its c<strong>on</strong>volutedincentive schemes into a single flat tax, withsimilar results.Colombia, El Salvador, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, Jamaica ,andMexico: eliminated distorti<strong>on</strong>s by cutting ineffectiveincentive schemes — and increased revenuesin the process.7. Increase revenue by keeping rate moderate:Russia: reduced corporate tax rate from 35percent to 24 percent in 2001, resulting in anannual average revenue growth of 14 percent overthe next three years, the lower rate resulted inincreased tax compliance.Egypt: reduced the corporate tax rate from 40percent to 20 percent in 2005. Indicati<strong>on</strong>s showthat there is an increase in tax compliance.248


Expansi<strong>on</strong>1. Distribute both positive and negative credit in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>in the registry sharing credit in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a need to put more emphasis <strong>on</strong> positivein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> like outstanding loans, assets, landpayment behaviour <strong>on</strong> accounts in good standing.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> public registries in Belgium, Brazil, andTurkey began sharing more positive in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.Backed by new laws, the Greek and H<strong>on</strong>g K<strong>on</strong>gprivate bureaus did the same. In Greece, thenumber of bureau c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s grew by morethan 50 percent and several new products <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>lenders were launched. In additi<strong>on</strong>, negativein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> like defaults and arrears should alsobe displayed.2. Improve data quality (re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms <strong>on</strong> registries):Bangladesh: the public registry raised the penalty<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> banks that withhold data from 2,000 takasto 500,000 takas and the penalty <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> disclosingcredit in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> to unauthorised parties from2,000 takas to 100,000 takas. As a result, theshare of banks submitting data <strong>on</strong> time jumpedfrom 25 percent to 95 percent.Mozambique: quality shot up after new regulati<strong>on</strong>sallowed the registry to fine banks <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>providing incomplete in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. More than adozen countries are improving data protecti<strong>on</strong>laws, which include incentives and safeguards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>quality.3. Make credit registry electr<strong>on</strong>ic:Pakistan: an <strong>on</strong>line system has been implementedto improve credit registries. Providing<strong>on</strong>line access is associated with more credit. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, this system might help spur commercialbanks to adopt credit-scoring technology, whichboth speeds up the lending process and reducesopportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> gender bias. Creditors can nowobtain in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> instantly.4. Introduce universal security <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> debtors andcreditors:Slovakia permitted debtors to use all movable assetsas collateral — present and future, tangibleand intangible, and abolished the requirements<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> specific descripti<strong>on</strong> of assets and debts. Sincethen, movables and receivables secure more than70 percent of all new business credit.5. Permit out of court collateral en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement:Spain: introduced out of court en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementthrough notaries executi<strong>on</strong>, allowing debtors andcreditors to agree <strong>on</strong> en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement methods. Timeto en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce was cut from more than <strong>on</strong>e year tothree m<strong>on</strong>ths.Slovakia: the gains from re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms were even larger.It took 560 days to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce a mortgage throughthe old system. Now it is possible to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce it in45 days.India: state-owned banks which account <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 90percent of lending, were permitted to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cesettlement out of court. On default the bank mustnotify the debtor. After a 60-day grace periodthe bank can seize the assets directly and sell bypublic aucti<strong>on</strong>. Creditors can expect to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cewithin nine m<strong>on</strong>ths.Ukraine also expanded the scope of assets thatcan be used as collateral, and gave secured creditorsfirst priority to their collateral and its proceeds.In additi<strong>on</strong>, it gave creditors the ability toen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce collateral privately, bypassing the lengthycourt procedures required be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e.Croatia cut several m<strong>on</strong>ths from en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement bymaking it harder <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> debtors to delay the en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementprocess. Movable collateral can now beseized and sold not just by the courts but also byauthorised private firms.Poland changed its bankruptcy laws in 2003.Previously, employees and taxes were paid be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ethe secured creditors up<strong>on</strong> liquidati<strong>on</strong>. Now, se-249


cured creditors have priority to the proceeds fromthe sale of their collateral.Armenia: since March 2004, the debtor automaticallyloses c<strong>on</strong>trol of his or her property to anadministrator <strong>on</strong> bankruptcy, increasing creditorrights.6. Introduce a new Leasing law:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> development of leasing as a complementarytool to bank loans provides an alternative soluti<strong>on</strong>,which can significantly expand access tocapital <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business.Benefits are: (a) an effective tool where capitalmarkets are less developed; (b) security arrangementsare simpler as it is provided by the leasedasset itself; (c) little cash is required, allowingthe lessee to c<strong>on</strong>serve cash or use it as workingcapital; (d) tax incentives often make it possible<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> SMEs to reduce income be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e taxes; and(e) promotes investment in capital equipment,increases competiti<strong>on</strong> in the financial sector, andfacilitates the transfer of new technology.Serbia and M<strong>on</strong>tenegro: since passing a new leasinglaw in May 2003, nine new leasing companieshave opened <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y expect toissue US$170 milli<strong>on</strong> in leases this year, roughlyhalf of all SME finance in the country.Uzbekistan: the level of leasing transacti<strong>on</strong>s wasextremely small, now there are 23 leasing companiesfinancing SMEs.Kazakhstan: after amending the tax law in 2003,six new lessors opened: leasing deals grew fromUS$57 milli<strong>on</strong> to US$89 milli<strong>on</strong> within threem<strong>on</strong>ths of the introducti<strong>on</strong> of the new legislati<strong>on</strong>,and the average deal size fell from US$190,000to under US$90,000, bringing leasing withinreach of more SMEs.Egypt: lease law introduced in 2000. Seven leasingcompanies cover most sectoral activities andmore than $5 billi<strong>on</strong> of financial leasing activitieswere introduced in the financial market.7. Repeal the normative acts, which authorisebanks to carry out functi<strong>on</strong>s that are not appropriate<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial intermediaries:Uzbekistan: banks act regularly as tax agents totrack timely tax payments and other mandatoryreturns by SMEs and to withdraw the outstandingamount of taxes and other payments owed tothe authority. Obviously, SMEs do not view banksas effective financial intermediaries. As a result,there is a need to repeal the normative acts,which authorise banks to carry out functi<strong>on</strong>s, thatare not appropriate.En<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing C<strong>on</strong>tracts1. Summary proceedings:Russia: the most popular re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in 2003 was theintroducti<strong>on</strong> of summary proceedings <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the collecti<strong>on</strong>of small debt and other smaller commercialdisputes. In late 2002, 60 percent of debtcollecti<strong>on</strong> cases in Moscow used this procedure.A summary procedure typically takes two m<strong>on</strong>thsfrom start to finish, nine m<strong>on</strong>ths less than a generalprocedure.2. Introducing case management:Case management can be described as a procedurein which the judge follows the case fromstart to end, reduces delays and increases usersatisfacti<strong>on</strong>. In additi<strong>on</strong>, this is very important <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>collecti<strong>on</strong> of debt. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> average durati<strong>on</strong> of debtcollecti<strong>on</strong> is five m<strong>on</strong>ths in rich countries wherejudges actively manage the case, and nearly 18m<strong>on</strong>ths in rich countries where judges d<strong>on</strong>’t.Finland: an electr<strong>on</strong>ic system of recording waspart of the case management. A judge can followeach case at any moment, reducing the time ittakes to reach resoluti<strong>on</strong>.Slovakia: this system has been implemented250


successfully without much additi<strong>on</strong>al cost. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>average time between filing and the first hearingwas cut from 73 days to 27 and the averagenumber of procedures from 23 to five, as judgeswere randomly assigned and could schedule thehearings without the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> withcourt clerks and other judges.3. Privatise en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement process and make itcompetitive:Private en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement or specialised public collecti<strong>on</strong>agencies to collect debt are more effective.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> best way to speed the recovery of overdue debtis by allowing competiti<strong>on</strong> in en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing judgments.Colombia scrapped the m<strong>on</strong>opoly of the courts toen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce judge’s ruling in 2003. Private companiesquickly moved into the business. As a result,time was cut by nearly two m<strong>on</strong>ths.Hungary and Slovakia also introduced privateen<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement.ExitWith higher recovery rates, banks are more willingto lend and more m<strong>on</strong>ey goes to new businessventures. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom to take <strong>on</strong> new ventures,and do so through an efficient process, ensuresthat a country’s people and capital are put totheir most productive uses.1. Specialised expertise:Provide specialised judges who deal with <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eclosureor bankruptcy cases. In developing countriesthis can be achieved by establishing a specializedcommercial secti<strong>on</strong> in the general court or in anadministrative agency.Peru: Its clerks and judges deal <strong>on</strong>ly with bankruptcyand debt recovery issues and not withdivorce or criminal cases.2. Limit appeals:Appeals are needed to resolve legitimate disputes.But too often they are abused and invoked<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> frivolous reas<strong>on</strong>s thus delaying an efficientoutcome. Limiting appeals, both at the outsetand during the procedure, increases recoveryrates.Australia, New Zealand and the United Kingdom:In <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eclosure proceedings, the creditors need<strong>on</strong>ly to prove that a payment is overdue. Appeal isnot possible.El Salvador: in c<strong>on</strong>trast, the debtor can appeal<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eclosure and delay its start by up to 16 m<strong>on</strong>ths.Appeals delay liquidati<strong>on</strong> or reorganisati<strong>on</strong>.Romania reduced each appeal from 30 to 10days. In additi<strong>on</strong>, appeal can be limited <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>legal grounds, not <strong>on</strong> the case facts, which arealready established and accepted by the judge atthe start of the case.Est<strong>on</strong>ia: allows the case to c<strong>on</strong>tinue duringappeal, avoiding disrupti<strong>on</strong> while providing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>disputes to be resolved. Allowing the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eclosureor bankruptcy case to c<strong>on</strong>tinue <strong>on</strong> appeal is associatedwith 20 percent less time in closing abusiness. And it almost doubles the chance ofkeeping it operating.Successful Initiatives taken by BusinessesThis secti<strong>on</strong> focuses <strong>on</strong> the initiatives taken fromthe private sector including in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesperspectives <strong>on</strong> their business rights and ensurethey can take full advantage of opportunities andmarkets.1. Appropriate legal frameworks that enshrine thefollowing as ec<strong>on</strong>omic rights:• Access to finance, raw material, and productmarkets at fair prices;• Access to transport and communicati<strong>on</strong> infrastructure;251


• Access to improved skills and technology;• Access to business development services;• Access to business incentive and trade promoti<strong>on</strong>packages: tax deferrals, subsidies, tradefairs, etc.;Examples:Fair Trade examplesVegcare, KenyaGrameen Bank, BangladeshSocial Fund, Egypt2. <strong>Legal</strong> property rights:• Private land• Intellectual property• Examples:land rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rural women in Mozambique, intellectualproperty rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenous peoplein southern Africa3. Use rights to public resources and appropriatez<strong>on</strong>ing regulati<strong>on</strong>s:• Rights to urban public land;• Rights to comm<strong>on</strong> and public resources: pastures,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests, and waterways;• Appropriate z<strong>on</strong>ing regulati<strong>on</strong>s stipulatingwhere and under what c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maloperators or businesses can operate in centralbusiness districts, suburban areas, and/orindustrial z<strong>on</strong>esExamples:Warwick Juncti<strong>on</strong> in Durban/e<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>kwini;Dedicated Built Market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Traditi<strong>on</strong>al MedicineVendors in Durban/e<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>kwini, SouthAfrica;Buy-Back Centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waste Collectors in Durban/e<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>kwini,South Africa;street vendors z<strong>on</strong>ing in Bangkok and Manila.4. Appropriate legal frameworks and standards<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> what in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators and businesses areallowed to buy and sell:• Appropriate laws and regulati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> what arelegal vs. illegal goods and services;• Appropriate product and process standards:e.g., public health and sanitati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cernsabout street food;• Marketing licenses <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> products and servicesExamples:Appropriate standards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> handling and processingof milk in Nicaragua, Kenya;market license <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> gum collectors in India.5. Appropriate legal tools to govern the transacti<strong>on</strong>and c<strong>on</strong>tractual relati<strong>on</strong>ships of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maloperators or businesses:• Bargaining and negotiating mechanisms/power;• <strong>Legal</strong> and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable c<strong>on</strong>tracts;• Grievance mechanisms;• C<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms;• Possibility of issuing shares;• Right to issue shares;• Right to advertise and protect brands andtrademarks;Examples:Brand name and advertisement <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> packagedcashew nuts in Senegal;brand name and fair prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ghanaianchocolate in UK;use of IT to market fish products in Senegal,India.6. <strong>Legal</strong> rights and mechanisms to provide in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maloperators and businesses with:• Temporary unemployment relief• Insurance of various kinds, including of land,house, equipment, and other means ofproducti<strong>on</strong>;• Bankruptcy rules;• Default rules;• Limited liability;252


• Asset protecti<strong>on</strong>;• Capital protecti<strong>on</strong>;• Capital withdrawal and transfer rules.Examples:Limited liability devices (ILD);Asset shielding devices (ILD; )Capital locking-in devices (ILD).7. <strong>Legal</strong> right <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators and businessesto join or <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m organisati<strong>on</strong>s, legal recogniti<strong>on</strong>of such organisati<strong>on</strong>s, and legal right ofrepresentati<strong>on</strong> of such organisati<strong>on</strong>s in relevantpolicy- making and rule-setting instituti<strong>on</strong>s:• Membership in mainstream business associati<strong>on</strong>s;• Membership in guilds or other associati<strong>on</strong>s ofsimilar types of entrepreneurs;• Representati<strong>on</strong> in relevant planning and rulesettingbodies.Examples:SEWA in India;StreetNet Internati<strong>on</strong>al;Ghana Trades Uni<strong>on</strong> C<strong>on</strong>gress;Catalunya affiliate of nati<strong>on</strong>al trade uni<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>federati<strong>on</strong>in Spain.An Integrated Ec<strong>on</strong>omy ApproachInstead of c<strong>on</strong>sidering the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omies as a dichotomy, practice is beginningto recognise them as a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum. Slowly butsurely, the more enlightened policymakers arebeginning to understand that legal empowermentin the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of reduced regulatory burden makessound business sense. New models, some of whichhave been illustrated above, are emerging whichrecognise that ec<strong>on</strong>omic policy has to promotean integrated approach to maximise social andec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunity and well-being of all socialand ec<strong>on</strong>omic strata. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> integrated and inclusiveec<strong>on</strong>omy approach recognises that if relati<strong>on</strong>shipsbetween different levels of ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity areto be anticipated, and made strategic and optimal,policy and instituti<strong>on</strong>al change <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sustained businesslinkages and skills development has to takeplace.To design and support the development of appropriatepolicy and instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an integratedec<strong>on</strong>omy, innovati<strong>on</strong>s emerging at the interfacebetween the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal have to beanalysed. Small producers and micro entrepreneursare daily developing strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> dealingwith the demands of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s whilethe latter have also developed ways of managingtheir inevitable encounter with those who arethe majority in the poorer countries of the world.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se coping strategies hold the clues to whatdevelopment interventi<strong>on</strong>s can build up<strong>on</strong> withinparticular cultures and ec<strong>on</strong>omies.Analysis of current practice offers several observati<strong>on</strong>sthat could guide movement froma bifurcated to an integrated, cohesive approachto entrepreneurship and ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity.First, in order to encourage greater engagementbetween established <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses and thesmaller enterprises, transacti<strong>on</strong> costs and risks ofsuch engagement have to be reduced.Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the public sector has to develop andimplement participatory processes so that supportis relevant to those <strong>on</strong> the fringes of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal activity.Third, change has to be negotiated throughiterative dialogue and partnerships that spanacross central and local governments, the privatesector, domestic capital markets, producer groupsand their social and ec<strong>on</strong>omic organisati<strong>on</strong>s.Fourth, the functi<strong>on</strong> in micro and small scaleentrepreneurial activity of ‘immediate and directreciprocities’ 94 has to be recognised; in many lowincomecommunities social groups and ec<strong>on</strong>omic253


Case Study:Identity, Voice, and Associati<strong>on</strong> in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy— <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> L<strong>on</strong>g Journey of Self-employed Women’s Associati<strong>on</strong> (Sewa), IndiaSEWA, established in 1972, is a trade uni<strong>on</strong>of low-income working women who earn theirlivelihoods by running small businesses, doingsubc<strong>on</strong>tracting work or selling their labour.With over 700,000 members in 2003, SEWA isthe first trade uni<strong>on</strong> of workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy not <strong>on</strong>ly in India, but also around theworld. It is also the largest trade uni<strong>on</strong> in India.SEWA’s objectives are to increase self—relianceas well as the ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social securityof its members. SEWA members fall into fourbroad occupati<strong>on</strong>al categories:• Hawkers and vendors, who sell a range of productsincluding vegetables, fruit and used clothingfrom baskets, push carts or small shops;• Home-based producers, who stitch garments,make patchwork quilts, roll hand-made cigarettes(bidis) or incense sticks, prepare snackfoods, recycle scrap metal, process agriculturalproducts, produce pottery or make craft items;• Manual labourers and service providers, whosell their labour (as cart-pullers, head-loadersor c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> workers), or who sell services(such as waste-paper picking, laundry servicesor domestic services); and• Rural producers, including small farmers,milk producers, animal rearers, nursery raisers/tenders, salt farmers and gum collectors.Over the years, SEWA has built a sisterhood ofinstituti<strong>on</strong>s, as follows:• SEWA Uni<strong>on</strong> (the primary membership-basedorganisati<strong>on</strong> to which all SEWA members bel<strong>on</strong>gand which provides overall governance ofthe organisati<strong>on</strong>);• SEWA Bank (which provides financial services,including both savings and credit);• Gujarat Mahila Cooperative Federati<strong>on</strong> (whichis resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> organising and supportingSEWA’s membership in several types of co-operatives);• Gujarat Mahila Housing SEWA Trust (whichprovides housing services);• SEWA Social Security (which provides health,childcare and insurance services);• Rural and Urban Branches of SEWA (whichoversee, respectively, its rural and urban activities,including the recruitment and organisingof members);• SEWA Marketing (which provides productdevelopment and marketing services);• SEWA Academy (which is resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>research, training, and communicati<strong>on</strong>).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first three are democratic membershipbasedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, governed by elected representatives.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> others are support instituti<strong>on</strong>sthat provide services of various kinds to SEWAmembers. Source: SEWA, 2003.groups are syn<strong>on</strong>ymous. How social relati<strong>on</strong>sand values other than material affect the modusoperandi of milli<strong>on</strong>s of entrepreneurs has to bebrought into ec<strong>on</strong>omic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s.Finally, the private sector has to be defined asincorporating all entrepreneurial activity in anycountry and should be seen as inclusive of both‘entrepreneurship inspired by opportunity’ and254


‘entrepreneurship inspired by necessity’. 95 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>latter was always known as the social welfareapproach; it now needs to be looked at througha business and wealth creati<strong>on</strong> lens. Within aninclusive ec<strong>on</strong>omy, entrepreneurship, whether<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal, would be supported by:• Removal of regulati<strong>on</strong>s that unduly inhibitprivate sector development;• An integrated perspective <strong>on</strong> micro, small,medium and large enterprises;• Linkages between various sizes of businesses;• Increased efficiency and productivity of thelabour <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce;• Enhanced competiti<strong>on</strong>;• Expanded markets. 96In making profitable markets more inclusive ofthe poor, risk mediati<strong>on</strong> is a fundamental c<strong>on</strong>cern.Formal instituti<strong>on</strong>s and large firms as wellas small and micro enterprises are all equally riskaverse, given the absence of adequate investorprotecti<strong>on</strong> or social safety nets in many countries.Acceptable risk is central in developing andsustaining trust. 97 So far, successful mediati<strong>on</strong>between large and small businesses has usuallybeen provided by guarantees through c<strong>on</strong>tractualand financial arrangements facilitated by credibleintermediaries such as d<strong>on</strong>ors, governments andNGOs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se models can be scaled up to becomemainstream if there is political will towards propoorpolicy and instituti<strong>on</strong>s that can move currentpractice towards greater parity and fairness inaccess to opportunity and assets.sector, in the nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se corporateentities of micro-enterprises can become thenatural partners of larger corporate entities thatmight outsource many of their operati<strong>on</strong>s andcomp<strong>on</strong>ent inputs to these entities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> problemsof dealing with large numbers of such enterprises,scattered as they are across the country,and maintaining quality c<strong>on</strong>trol have discouragedwhat might otherwise have been a mostcost-effective partnership between the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maland in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector. Larger corporate entities ofmicro-enterprises would eliminate both the costand managerial problems associated with buildingthis linkage and could open new horiz<strong>on</strong>s ofopportunity that might lead the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sectorto become <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally integrated with the macroec<strong>on</strong>omy.98To Sum Up<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are rich, real life examples of ‘businessrights’ successes from all over the world that canbe borrowed and implemented, with necessary improvementsand modificati<strong>on</strong>s to suit local envir<strong>on</strong>mentsand priorities. What is needed <strong>on</strong> the partof both the authorities and business participantsis openness in critically evaluating real-life cases,and in adopting and adapting as necessary thosewith potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> successful implementati<strong>on</strong>.Another example of integrati<strong>on</strong> is the prospect oflarge numbers of micro-enterprises, living precariouslives in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector, coming togetherto <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m large corporate entities, and competing innati<strong>on</strong>al and global markets. This could providea new perspective <strong>on</strong> the role of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal255


6. Pursuing the agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>changeOver the last two decades, much attenti<strong>on</strong> hasbeen paid to legal and regulatory instituti<strong>on</strong>s andto their influence <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic outcomes. It isrecogniti<strong>on</strong> of the importance of good governancein advancing ec<strong>on</strong>omic development initiatives.As a result, much development assistance isbeing directed towards re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of nati<strong>on</strong>al legalcodes, public instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and bureaucraticprocesses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> anticipated result is a legalinfrastructure c<strong>on</strong>ducive to market-led ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth. However, the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m movement has notfully (perhaps <strong>on</strong>ly marginally) addressed themultifarious issues of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity.Deregulati<strong>on</strong> was expected to result in significantshifts of entrepreneurial activity from in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malto <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal. But, as pointed out earlier the scaleof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity is actually growing,not decreasing. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector is hereto stay. At the same time, policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, thatstrengthens what works <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the working poor andresp<strong>on</strong>ds to what does not, is l<strong>on</strong>g overdue.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, regulati<strong>on</strong>s, and instituti<strong>on</strong>s governingcommercial relati<strong>on</strong>s need to reflect the realitythat most ec<strong>on</strong>omic units are very small with fewhired workers and that many of the working pooroperate <strong>on</strong> their own account. Also, biases inexisting laws, regulati<strong>on</strong>s, and instituti<strong>on</strong>s thatfavour large enterprises over small <strong>on</strong>es, and menover women, need to be addressed. Meanwhile,in the absence of new and more appropriate laws,regulati<strong>on</strong>s and instituti<strong>on</strong>s, most in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesseswill remain unprotected, insecure, andvulnerable.Business-related re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms are now really comingunder closer scruitiny. 99 In fact, there is anincreasing demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to c<strong>on</strong>tain ‘valuebased policies, strategies and instituti<strong>on</strong>s’ thatwill bring l<strong>on</strong>g-term sustainable benefits to thepoor in general and to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises inparticular.What is needed at this juncture are policiesregarding <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> that not <strong>on</strong>ly simplify<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malities or improve the quality of regulati<strong>on</strong>,but also increase the value of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>provided by public registers to their users, bothpublic and private. This is because business <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>is an ordinary productive process thatincurs costs but also provides valuable publicand private services. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> private services reducefirms’ transacti<strong>on</strong> costs in many of their c<strong>on</strong>tracts,and the public services facilitate the workof the administrati<strong>on</strong> in its dealings with firms.In other words, ‘the main priority should not beto reduce the cost of business <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> — acost paid <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>ce — but rather to reduce transacti<strong>on</strong>costs in all business dealings. . . . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>restructuring of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malities is in itself insufficient<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> reducing total transacti<strong>on</strong> costs. It may alsobe a costly distracti<strong>on</strong>. It is necessary, rather, toenhance the value of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>.’ 100Addressing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, is a multi-facetedpropositi<strong>on</strong> requiring a thorough understandingof the factors that create and drive in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality.Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m initiatives may also require that the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector be re-defined to accommodatemany of the principles and values which characterisethe vibrancy and resilience of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsector. Clearly, there is no single approach tore<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m but there are essential and comm<strong>on</strong> principlesthat must be observed. Three key <strong>on</strong>es are:c<strong>on</strong>text specificity, a participatory and genderedapproach, and recogniti<strong>on</strong> of legal empowermentof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses as a governance issue.This secti<strong>on</strong> sums up our discussi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> what thepromise of legal empowerment holds with respectto unlocking the productive capacities of the256


milli<strong>on</strong>s who operate poor, micro in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses.Changes have to be C<strong>on</strong>text SpecificAlthough development interventi<strong>on</strong>s tend to favourre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m through standardised, ‘best practice’ instituti<strong>on</strong>al<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, 101 what is required is an empiricallygrounded perspective using c<strong>on</strong>text-specificresearch, organisati<strong>on</strong>al innovati<strong>on</strong> and politicalentrepreneurship rather than the importati<strong>on</strong> ofinstituti<strong>on</strong>al templates (‘toolkits’) <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ged elsewhere.102 Because rules are at <strong>on</strong>ce c<strong>on</strong>stituentelements of cultural norms and values as muchas they are embodied in commercial codes andc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s, attempts at ‘legal empowerment’need to engage if not with that full spectrum thenat least with a more complete awareness of thespectrum’s existence and importance. 103<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e c<strong>on</strong>text-specificity is a fundamentalrequirement in moving towards change. Thisspecificity must also extend to the reality ofdifferent categories of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses inspecific locales and industries. Any policy orinstituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m has to recognise and supportboth the self-employed (differentiating betweenmicro-entrepreneurs and own-account operators)and wage workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>lack of recogniti<strong>on</strong> and understanding of thesebasic comp<strong>on</strong>ents of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy oftenhinders the development of appropriate policy.Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Processes Must beParticipatory and Gender Resp<strong>on</strong>sivePolicy and instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m should be participatoryand inclusive and allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policies tobe developed through c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses, and through c<strong>on</strong>sensus of relevantgovernment departments, the organisati<strong>on</strong>s ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses and other appropriate socialactors. In order to have a voice, those who arein the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy must be organised andtheir ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to organise into associati<strong>on</strong> andcooperatives at every level should be encouraged.In order to organise, the working poor have to beallowed the space and resources to associate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>a comm<strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic purpose and without politicalmanipulati<strong>on</strong>.Of course, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulating appropriate policies andstrategies is not an easy task. However, with theinvolvement of the organisati<strong>on</strong>s that representin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses it is likely to succeed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>way <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward has to be <strong>on</strong>e of negotiated soluti<strong>on</strong>s,and these negotiati<strong>on</strong>s have to be aboutrights and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities. While the inclusi<strong>on</strong>of the voice of all stakeholders in making policyis essential to its success, the input of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malworkers and their organisati<strong>on</strong>s, based <strong>on</strong> recogniti<strong>on</strong>of their right to organise, is crucial.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> voice of women has to be clearly heard inthis process. In most regi<strong>on</strong>s of the world, alarger share of the female than of the male work<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceis in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and, within thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, more women tend to be c<strong>on</strong>centratedin lower-return segments than are men.As a result, even within the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,there is a significant gender gap in earnings andin the benefits and protecti<strong>on</strong> af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ded by work.Understanding relati<strong>on</strong>s between men and women,their different positi<strong>on</strong>s in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy andtheir access to and c<strong>on</strong>trol of resources, is crucialto understanding the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, wherea gendered approach is a pro-poor approach.Supporting women’s work will, in effect, lead tosupport <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor households and poor children.<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusiness should be prioritised as agovernance issue<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process should be based <strong>on</strong> an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>medunderstanding of the ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>tribu-257


Case Study:Technology and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector: Fishing with Mobile Ph<strong>on</strong>esA Fisherman <strong>on</strong> the coast of Kerala, in southernIndia, faces the dilemma: in the situati<strong>on</strong>of good catch, should he or she sell the fish(sardines) at the local beach or or travel to amarket farther away? If he or she stays at thelocal beach , prices could be low due to oversupply, but travelling would be a costly decisi<strong>on</strong>in terms of transportati<strong>on</strong> cost and time toanother market. Moreover, each market remainsopen <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>ly a couple of hours be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e dawn andfish are perishable; any that cannot be sold willhave to be dumped into the sea.According to a research by Robert Jensen, untilthe introducti<strong>on</strong> of mobiles ph<strong>on</strong>es in 1997 fishepeople used to stick with their home marketsall the time. This was wasteful: <strong>on</strong> average, 5-8percent of the total catch was lost. He noted, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, <strong>on</strong> January 14th 1997, ‘Eleven fishermenat Badagara beach ended up throwing awaytheir catches, yet <strong>on</strong> that day there were 27 buyersat markets within 15km (about nine miles)who would have bought their fish.’After the introducti<strong>on</strong> of mobile ph<strong>on</strong>es therewas remarkable change in fishermen’s behaviour,the price of fish, and the amount of waste.Fishermen started to buy ph<strong>on</strong>es and use themto call coastal markets while still at sea. Insteadof selling their fish at home beach aucti<strong>on</strong>s, thefishermen would call around to find the bestprice. In <strong>on</strong>e area, the proporti<strong>on</strong> of fishermenwho ventured bey<strong>on</strong>d their home markets to selltheir catches jumped from zero to around 35percent. At that point, no fish were wasted andthe variati<strong>on</strong> in prices fell dramatically. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>‘law of <strong>on</strong>e price’ — the idea that in efficientmarket identical goods should cost the same— had come into effect, in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of a singlerate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sardines al<strong>on</strong>g the coast... This moreefficient market benefited every<strong>on</strong>e. Fishermen’sprofits rose by 8 percent <strong>on</strong> average andc<strong>on</strong>sumer prices fell by 4 percent <strong>on</strong> average.Higher profits meant the ph<strong>on</strong>es typically paid<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themselves within two m<strong>on</strong>ths. And the benefitsare enduring, rather than <strong>on</strong>e-off.’This shows the importance of the free flow ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> to ensure that markets work efficiently,which in turn improve welfare.ti<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses and serve to mainstreamthe c<strong>on</strong>cerns of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesin those instituti<strong>on</strong>s that deal with ec<strong>on</strong>omicplanning and development. In the past, themanagement or regulati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal activitieshas often been relegated to social policy departmentsor, in urban areas, to those departments(such as the police or traffic) that deal with lawand order issues. Locating governance of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy in traffic, health, policy orsocial departments ignores its ec<strong>on</strong>omic aspects.Instituti<strong>on</strong>s that govern the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omyshould be those dealing with ec<strong>on</strong>omic planningand development. That is why this report hasemphasised that re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m has to be couched withinan integrated ec<strong>on</strong>omy approach where in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maland <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal are seen as equally important ec<strong>on</strong>omicplayers, each demanding equal attenti<strong>on</strong>in nati<strong>on</strong>al governance laws and instituti<strong>on</strong>s.Strategies and Instituti<strong>on</strong>s to SupportIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses258


In developing and promoting new approaches,some c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s and innovati<strong>on</strong>s outlinedbelow could be c<strong>on</strong>sidered. 104Market-based instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> capacity of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses to operate <strong>on</strong>more equal terms in the market place dependsgreatly <strong>on</strong> their capacity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> collective acti<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> weakness of the poor in the market placeoriginates in their isolati<strong>on</strong>. Here, investmentsin instituti<strong>on</strong>s, whether sp<strong>on</strong>sored by NGOs orrepresenting collective acti<strong>on</strong> by the poor in the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of marketing cooperatives, or corporate bodiesof the poor, remain crucial interventi<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>issue there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e remains, posed as a challenge: toinvest the poor and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses with capacityto develop the financial and organisati<strong>on</strong>alstrength to sell products and services, at a timeand in a market that offers them the best terms,or to simply watch as they c<strong>on</strong>tinue to sell theirgoods out of distress or just the need to subsist.Taking up the challenge positively demandsinterventi<strong>on</strong>s in the macro-credit market to underwritesuch marketing ventures, the designingof instituti<strong>on</strong>s which aggregate the market powerof the poor, and the deployment of professi<strong>on</strong>alswith management skills and especially trained toassist the poor in up-scaling their participati<strong>on</strong> inthe market ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Adding value and supply chain to the labour of thepoor and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesMany NGOs around the world provide marketingservices to the poor, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> particular commodities,in particular markets. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> best service that canbe provided is to help the poor and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesadd value to their labours by moving upmarketthrough either agro-processing or providinginputs to the corporate sector. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> pi<strong>on</strong>eeringrole of Amul Dairy in India and, more recently,BRAC, are instructive model examples. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y enablesmall dairy farmers, or just poor householdsthat own a cow bought through a micro-creditloan, to become part of a milk processing chain,thus enabling the poor to share in the profits fromselling pasteurised milk or cheese in the metropolitanmarket. Such initiatives may be taken <strong>on</strong>estep further by financially empowering the vastbody of small farmers servicing the private agroprocessingsector, as well as handloom weavers,to become equity stakeholders in the upstreamenterprises that could add value to their produceor abour.Taking micro-credit out of theghetto 105Nowhere is there a greater need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> developing amacro-perspective <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty eradicati<strong>on</strong> than inthe area of m<strong>on</strong>etary policy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> instruments ofm<strong>on</strong>etary policy appear to be exclusively targetedtowards ensuring macroec<strong>on</strong>omic stability, moderatinginflati<strong>on</strong> and meeting the credit needs ofthe corporate sector. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial needs of thepoor, <strong>on</strong>ce left to the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector, have nowbeen segregated in the micro-credit market. Thisapartheid within the m<strong>on</strong>etary system remains amajor anomaly.Indeed, it can however be argued that by its verynature, micro-credit can never aspire to eradicatepoverty since it <strong>on</strong>ly addresses <strong>on</strong>e comp<strong>on</strong>entof the various markets that c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> the lives ofthe rural poor. It is arguable that by locking thepoor into the micro-credit system, based <strong>on</strong> thefiduciary resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of the household, theyhave been excluded from participating in themacro ec<strong>on</strong>omy, isolated from collective acti<strong>on</strong>,and c<strong>on</strong>demned to live <strong>on</strong> the fringes of the povertyline. It is, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, not surprising that thosecountries with the most substantive exposure tomicro-credit, remain mired in poverty. However, it259


is not the aim to diminish the enormous c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>of micro-credit in alleviating poverty and distress,as well as enhancing the self-worth of thepoor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is, today, no reas<strong>on</strong> why such organisati<strong>on</strong>s,of the maturity of Grameen Bank, shouldnot graduate into the macro finance system byaccessing the deposits of the public and evenmarketing its assets at the global level, throughsuch financial instruments as securitisati<strong>on</strong>, thatare in widespread use in more advanced financialsystems.Anumber of commercial banks are alreadyusing NGOs and community-based organisati<strong>on</strong>sto retail banking services to the poor. Otherexamples include Scotia Bank in the Caribbeanand ANZ Bank in the Pacific Islands, which haveventured into ‘Banking <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor’ and ‘MobileBanking <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Villages’. In Egypt, the Social Fund,Credit Guarantee Company and Micro-financeNGOs are not <strong>on</strong>ly successful providers of creditto in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses but also organisers of permanentexhibiti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> MSMEs’ products, offeringentrepreneurial training and outreach services topoor enterprises.Mutual funds <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poorApart from the issue of redesigning m<strong>on</strong>etarypolicy to deliver credit to the poor, the m<strong>on</strong>etarysystem also needs to design special financialinstruments to attract these micro-savings intothe corporate sector, particularly where it can bestructured to serve the poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mutual fund isbut <strong>on</strong>e instituti<strong>on</strong>al mechanism to link the poorto the corporate sector. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> underlying premise ofthe mutual fund is the noti<strong>on</strong> of creating possibilities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor to own corporate assets. Opportunitiesare there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e opening <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> linking thefarmers to the agro-processing corporate sector bygiving them an equity stake in such enterprises.At the same time, the agro-corporati<strong>on</strong>s shouldBox 4 Largest multi-nati<strong>on</strong>alcompany has 2.3 milli<strong>on</strong> ruralpoor women as shareholders<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> largest single <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign corporate investment inBangladesh is manifested in the GrameenPh<strong>on</strong>e experience.GrameenPh<strong>on</strong>e is a commercial joint ventureto provide cellular ph<strong>on</strong>e services. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> companycurrently has two milli<strong>on</strong> subscribers which coverstwo-thirds of all ph<strong>on</strong>e subscribers in Bangladesh.Telenor, the largest mobile ph<strong>on</strong>e company in Norwayholds a 51 percent ownership stake in Grameen-Ph<strong>on</strong>e and has so far invested over US$600 milli<strong>on</strong>in the joint venture making it the largest single<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign investor in the country. Grameen Telecom,a sister organisati<strong>on</strong> of Grameen Bank, ownedby 2.3 milli<strong>on</strong> poor rural women in Bangladesh,owns 35 percent of Grameen Ph<strong>on</strong>e. As and whenGrameenPh<strong>on</strong>e goes public it will be possible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>these rural women to become direct stakeholdersin the largest private enterprise in the country. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>goal of Grameen Bank is to make these poor womeninto the majority owners of the company as Telenormeets their commitment to gradually divest theirequity stake in the company to local investors. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>prospect of poor rural women in Bangladesh owning<strong>on</strong>e of the largest corporate enterprises in the countrycould have a trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming effect <strong>on</strong> how the poorperceive their role in the nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omy.be motivated to invest in improving productivityand capacities of their rural partners. An interestingpossibility of enabling the poor to own corporateassets is provided in Bangladesh.Financial policy need not limit itself to ownershipof corporate assets but could also be restructuredto ensure that all assets, from urban land, to realestate development, and from banks to corporatetrading houses, could be redesigned to accommodatethe poor as equity partners. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> two260


instituti<strong>on</strong>al instruments to make this possibleremain the mutual fund and the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> privatelimited companies to trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m themselves intopublic limited companies. Here m<strong>on</strong>etary and fiscalpolicy can provide incentives to encourage thecorporatisati<strong>on</strong> of private wealth al<strong>on</strong>g with thereservati<strong>on</strong> of space <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> equity ownership of thiswealth by the poor.Instituti<strong>on</strong>alising the collectiveidentity of poor and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses 106Suggesti<strong>on</strong>s about building a collective identity<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses throughspecially c<strong>on</strong>structed instituti<strong>on</strong>s derives fromthe need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor to claim a place in societythat is more commensurate with their numbers.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor remain disempowered because they areisolated; bring them together and they emergeas a major <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy, in society and,eventually, in the political arena. Instituti<strong>on</strong>alarrangements that can add value to the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>magenda are:a) Corporati<strong>on</strong>s of the poor and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses:Community-based or self-help organisati<strong>on</strong>s(CBOs) of the poor, cooperatives andactivity-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s, that bring groupsof the poor together, should aspire to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ge aninstituti<strong>on</strong>al identity. Corporatising the CBOs willprovide the legal foundati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> collective acti<strong>on</strong>,to enable these bodies of the poor to accesscredit, enter into c<strong>on</strong>tractual relati<strong>on</strong>ships anddeal with internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> preciselegal pers<strong>on</strong>a of these corporati<strong>on</strong>s may varyfrom limited liability companies, with the poor asequity owners, to cooperatives with the poor aspartner members. But the comm<strong>on</strong> feature of allsuch corporate entities of the poor is that theymust operate in the market place and generateincome rather than limiting themselves to surviveas savings and loan associati<strong>on</strong>s.b) Corporatising micro-enterprises: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> prospectof large numbers of micro-enterprises, livingprecarious lives in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector, comingtogether to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer large corporate entities thatwould compete in nati<strong>on</strong>al and global markets,provides a new perspective <strong>on</strong> the role of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector in the nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>secorporate entities of micro-enterprises can becomethe natural partners of larger corporate entitiesthat could outsource many operati<strong>on</strong>s andcomp<strong>on</strong>ent inputs to them... <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> larger corporateentities of micro-enterprises would eliminate boththe cost and managerial problems associated withbuilding this linkage and open up new horiz<strong>on</strong>sof opportunity to the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mallyintegrate with the macro ec<strong>on</strong>omy.Bangladesh provides technology upgrading,quality c<strong>on</strong>trol, credits and marketing services tolarge numbers of handicraft enterprises acrossthe country. However it still deals with theseenterprises as clients who are helped by accessto credit, markets and skill development. BRAChas to take the next step of aggregating theseproducers into a larger corporate entity wherethey acquire an equity stake in the final profitsof the enterprise. Such a corporate entity hasbeen developed in India with the Papad cooperativewhere around 100,000 small householdenterprises producing the spicy snack c<strong>on</strong>diment,the Papad, have been aggregated to become thelargest single supply source of quality papads togrocery stores across the country.c) Micro-insurance — Protecting In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses:Micro-credit can help the poor rise abovepoverty. Micro-insurance can help by providingprotecti<strong>on</strong> against certain perils; micro-insurancecomplements other financial and socialservices. Because they often live and do business261


in risky envir<strong>on</strong>ments — in urban shanty townswith unsanitary c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, in rural areas pr<strong>on</strong>eto droughts or floods — the poor and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses are more vulnerable than the rest ofthe populati<strong>on</strong> to perils such as illness, accidentaldeath and disability, theft or fire, agriculturallosses, natural or manmade disasters. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y arealso the least able to cope with crisis when itoccurs. Micro-insurance with the use of technologyhas been successfully been introduced in anumber of countries:In Uganda and Malawi, some insurance providersissue smart-cards to poor policyholders toc<strong>on</strong>firm that they are who they say they are, andcan instantly provide in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> their level ofcoverage and whether the premium has been paid.In the Philippines, insurers have minimised thetransacti<strong>on</strong> costs of collecting many small premiumsby allowing people to pay via their mobileph<strong>on</strong>es.In India, a barcode system is being tested as away of managing client in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> barcodestickers are especially useful <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> illiterate clientswho can attach them <strong>on</strong>to pre-addressed envelopesto identify themselves.Business Rights — providevalue-based change process.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rati<strong>on</strong>ale <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> changes in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessessuch that some elements and advantagesof <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> are incorporated is rooted in awider appreciati<strong>on</strong> of how both individuals andbusinesses can be disadvantaged by operatingoutside the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy and the recogniti<strong>on</strong>that there are benefits to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>. Neverthelessmicro-entrepreneurs make an ec<strong>on</strong>omiccalculati<strong>on</strong> al<strong>on</strong>g the lines of a cost-benefitanalysis, which determines a minimum thresholdof participati<strong>on</strong> in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal arrangements <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> whichthe costs remain lower than the benefits. Somefirms will there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e choose to participate in <strong>on</strong>lya subset of instituti<strong>on</strong>s at any point in time. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, benefits and costs of participating in a<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal c<strong>on</strong>text vary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> firms of different size andexpected lifetime. It would <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance seem thatyoung, inefficient and small firms are disproporti<strong>on</strong>atelyin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> chart below illustrates the phases an enterprisemight hypothetically go through be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e itbecomes an official <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprise. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> chartalso illustrates that the transiti<strong>on</strong> from an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malto a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal status is gradual and that it isimportant to initiate the relevant processes thatcould assist enterprises to reach a more <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malexistence. Any interventi<strong>on</strong>s in support of movingenterprises towards a more <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal existenceshould be prioritised and c<strong>on</strong>centrated <strong>on</strong> wherethe maximum effects can be reached. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> waythat the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises themselves rank theproblems that they are facing would indicate howto prioritise interventi<strong>on</strong>s.In order to make a smooth transiti<strong>on</strong> from in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malto <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal there needs to be a str<strong>on</strong>g foundati<strong>on</strong>of: a) rule of law and access to justice; b)good governance and protecti<strong>on</strong> of basic rights(human, legal, property and labour); c) str<strong>on</strong>gphysical and social infrastructure; d) politicaland ec<strong>on</strong>omic stability, and e) c<strong>on</strong>ducive and fairbusiness envir<strong>on</strong>ment.Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, the causes of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality are complexand defy simple explanati<strong>on</strong>s. C<strong>on</strong>sequently,the trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> can <strong>on</strong>ly be tackled successfullyby a linking set of policy initiatives thatdeliver both pull and push pressures. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> DemandPull and Supply Push measures are brieflyhighlighted in Chart 1. Demand ‘Pull’ initiativesinclude: access to finance, capital and credit;tax relief and incentives, titling, public procure-262


Figure 5<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal EnterprisesSUPPLY PUSH• Regulatory Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms• Reducingadministrativebarriers• Af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dableBusiness Fees• Simplified Taxati<strong>on</strong>• AccessibleBusiness Licensingand Registrati<strong>on</strong>• ReducingCorrupti<strong>on</strong>• Adaptable Labour<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>sGradual Transiti<strong>on</strong> through Business RightsIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malSubsistenceBusinessesUnofficialBusinessesPartlyOfficialBusinessesFormalSustainableBusinessesDEMAND PULL• Access toFinance andCredit• Tax relief andincentives• Titling• PublicProcurementOpportunities• SkillsDevelopment• EntrepreneurialtrainingRULE OF LAW& ACCESS TO JUSTICEBASIC RIGHTS(HUMAN, LEGAL,PROPERTY & LABOUR)PHYSICAL & SOCIALINFRASTRUCTUREPOLITICAL & ECONOMICSTABILITY & GOODGOVERNANCECONDUCIVE &FAIR BUSINESSENVIRONMENTPILLARS OF FOUNDATION FOR FORMALISATIONment opportunities, skills development, entrepreneurialtraining, etc. Supply ‘Push’ initiativesare regulatory re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, reducing administrativebarriers, af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable business and licensing fees,accessible business and licensing and registrati<strong>on</strong>procedures; reducing corrupti<strong>on</strong>; adaptablelabour laws, etc. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> chart further highlightsthat the number of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises movingtowards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sustainable enterprises is smallcompared to the huge size of subsistence in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises.Formalisati<strong>on</strong> may there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e be seen as anincremental process that begins by introducingappropriate incentives and benefits of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality,then progressively en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces compliance with thecosts and regulati<strong>on</strong>s associated with operating<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally which would depend <strong>on</strong> the size, output,or locati<strong>on</strong> of the enterprises. Once c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s aremet, the working poor in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omywould be entitled to the benefits of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and,at the same time, they would be enabled to complywith the duties of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>Pillars of Change<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sustainability of any proposed re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m toa country’s governing instituti<strong>on</strong>s depends <strong>on</strong>public recogniti<strong>on</strong> of the changes to be made.Recogniti<strong>on</strong> will thus depend <strong>on</strong> the capacity ofthe re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m to be legitimised within the public’scultural and social milieu. Failure may preventthe successes of legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that are otherwisecognizant of larger policy aims to promotemarket-driven ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. For Sub-SaharanAfrica, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, failure to incorporate widely263


accepted customary <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms could mean outrightrejecti<strong>on</strong> by the private sector. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, indetermining what can be d<strong>on</strong>e to legally empowerin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses to better access the opportunities,finances, services and facilities of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsector, <strong>on</strong>e would have to take into accountthat which already works.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> recommendati<strong>on</strong>s of the working group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Chapter 4 of this report may be summarised indescripti<strong>on</strong>s of five proposed pillars of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m:Pillar 1: Adopt an inclusive and integratedapproach to ec<strong>on</strong>omic development so that thereis legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> and empowerment of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses.<strong>Legal</strong>ly empowering small in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesrun by poor individuals or households should beseen as a central pillar of a just society and acentral strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> reducing poverty and inequality.This means that policies and global ec<strong>on</strong>omicprivilege, which is geared at present to the elitesand large enterprises, have to change to becomeinclusive of the billi<strong>on</strong>s at the bottom of the ec<strong>on</strong>omicpyramid. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se billi<strong>on</strong>s are the producersand c<strong>on</strong>sumers who make markets profitable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the privileged. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir share has to be duly recognisedthrough much greater public and privatesector cognisance and support to small firmsand enterprises. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, with its flexibilityand space <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> milli<strong>on</strong>s to engage productivelyin ec<strong>on</strong>omies, is here to stay. Official and legalresp<strong>on</strong>se needs to recognise what works in thissector and strengthen and integrate these innovati<strong>on</strong>sinto an inclusive integrated approach towealth creati<strong>on</strong>.Pillar 2: Support legal empowerment througha package of commercial rights underlined inpolicies and instituted and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced throughregulatory bodies.Commercial rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs/operatorsinclude, but are not limited to, propertyrights, labour rights, right to social protecti<strong>on</strong>,right to be organised and represented in policymakingand rule-setting instituti<strong>on</strong>s and processes,and the right of access to justice in a transparentand equitable manner. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rights of the morevulnerable groups — the own-account operators,including single-pers<strong>on</strong> operators and those whowork in family businesses or <strong>on</strong> family farms— must also be addressed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se commercialrights should address all categories of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprise, and include the following provisi<strong>on</strong>s:a) Basic commercial rights: right to work, includingthe right to vend; right to a work space(public land, private residences), includingrelated basic infrastructure (shelter, electricity,water, sanitati<strong>on</strong>);b)Intermediary commercial rights: right togovernment incentives and support (includingprocurement, tax holidays, export licensing,export promoti<strong>on</strong>); right to public infrastructure(transport and communicati<strong>on</strong>);c) Advanced commercial rights: relevant <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> larger,more advanced in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises.Pillar 3: Reduce Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘defi cits’ of thosewho work in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally.This means support to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses in the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of:• Participati<strong>on</strong> in policy processes of a representativevoice of the working poor in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. Recogniti<strong>on</strong> and correcti<strong>on</strong> of thebias in existing commercial policies, regulati<strong>on</strong>s,laws and procedures favouring largerfirms and enterprises. Extensi<strong>on</strong> of governmentincentives and procurements to the smallestin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises;• Facilitati<strong>on</strong> as appropriate of backward and264


<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward linkages <strong>on</strong> fair terms between largerand smaller firms;• Promoti<strong>on</strong> of market access and fair trade <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>smaller firms and enterprises;• Social protecti<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators throughproperty, health, life, disability insurance;• Adequate and relevant retraining, life-l<strong>on</strong>glearning, and other support to labour mobility.Pillar 4: Broaden access of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessto financial services and support innovati<strong>on</strong> infinancial products and processes. This requiresthat there be:• Awareness in both <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal creditsystems of the way the working poor use creditand the barriers and often inappropriate rulesin <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal lending procedures;• <strong>Legal</strong> and administrative processes in placewhich make the processing of collateral includingsocial collateral cheaper, transparent andfaster;• <strong>Legal</strong>ly recognised and mutually negotiated riskmediati<strong>on</strong> processes in place <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> both the lendersand borrowers from in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal business;• Support to innovati<strong>on</strong> in financial products andservices with a view to deepening their outreach.Pillar 5: Engage in evidence-based re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are now hundreds of good practice examplesthat illustrate how the c<strong>on</strong>straints of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malbusinesses have been successfully addressedaround the world. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se examples should bestudied and the less<strong>on</strong>s learnt should be groupedaccording to what c<strong>on</strong>straint or need was beingaddressed and the policy less<strong>on</strong> drawn from theexperience. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m that ensures shouldbe participatory and targeted to the realities of thedifferent sub-sectors in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>sThis report has outlined how the process ofachieving greater legal empowerment (throughbusiness rights and access to the advantagesof <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong>) can and should take different<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Incentives to encourage in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneursto actively engage in the change processmust show actual benefits to their livelihoods andtheir well-being. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se incentives are essentiallywhat would result if the barriers to entry intoand/or interacti<strong>on</strong> with <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and legal ec<strong>on</strong>omicactivity were addressed. Incentives could be inthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of• Simplified registrati<strong>on</strong> procedures and progressiveregistrati<strong>on</strong> fees;• A supportive investment climate and a businessenabling envir<strong>on</strong>ment;• Fair commercial transacti<strong>on</strong>s between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal firms;• Appropriate legal and regulatory frameworks,including: en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable commercial c<strong>on</strong>tracts;private property rights; more equitable use ofpublic land; and tax-funded incentives, suchas government procurement, tax rebates, taxfundedsubsidies, and incentive packages.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se incentives would have to be supported atthe same time by appropriate and customisedfinancial, business development, and marketingservices. Mechanisms and financing arrangementsto provide social protecti<strong>on</strong> to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malproducers have to be put into place and policyand instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m undertaken in a participatorymanner. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs,both women and men, would be bestensured through proactive and iterative dialogue— <strong>on</strong> an <strong>on</strong>going basis — with representatives ofassociati<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs.265


Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s and Key MessagesObjectives of Empowerment Process<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businessesshould seek to promote an appropriate mix to differenttypes of business rights, and the pursuit ofthe following sets of objectives:Broad Objectives• Reducing regulatory burden;• Reducing barriers to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal markets and instituti<strong>on</strong>s;• Increasing assets, including property rights;• Expanding market access;• Improving terms of doing business;• Extending legal and social protecti<strong>on</strong>;• Increasing organisati<strong>on</strong> and representati<strong>on</strong>.Specific Objectives — Depending <strong>on</strong> their sizeand potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> growth, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses needsome combinati<strong>on</strong> of the following business rights:• Basic business rights: right to work, includingright to vend; right to a work space (includingpublic land and private residences), and relatedbasic infrastructure (shelter, electricity, water,sanitati<strong>on</strong>).• Intermediary business rights: right to governmentincentives and support (includingprocurement, tax holidays, export licensing,export promoti<strong>on</strong>); right to public infrastructure(transport and communicati<strong>on</strong>).• Advanced business rights: ILD set of legaltools, such as bankruptcy rules, relevant <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>larger, more developed, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises.Means to Meet ObjectivesDifferent Instruments — Policies and laws, regulati<strong>on</strong>sand procedures, business developmentinfrastructure, and organisati<strong>on</strong> and representati<strong>on</strong>of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal business.Policy and Regulatory Envir<strong>on</strong>ment - <strong>Legal</strong> empowermentof in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal business requires a policyand regulatory envir<strong>on</strong>ment that:• Provides legal identity to the working poor asproducers or traders;• includes representative voice of the workingpoor in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy;• Recognises and addresses the bias in existingcommercial policies, regulati<strong>on</strong>s, laws, andprocedures that favour larger firms/enterprises;• Seeks to extend government incentives andprocurements to the smallest in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises;• Seeks to build backward and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward linkages<strong>on</strong> fair terms between larger and smaller firms;• Seeks to promote market access and fair trade<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> smaller firms and enterprises;• Promotes social protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal operators(property, health, life, disability insurance)plus retraining, life-l<strong>on</strong>g learning, and othersupport to mobility.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Formalisati<strong>on</strong> Debate:In resp<strong>on</strong>se to the questi<strong>on</strong> of whether and howto <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malise in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>should highlight the point that <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> hasdifferent dimensi<strong>on</strong>s:• Expanding <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal employment opportunities.• Creating incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malise, including1) Simplified registrati<strong>on</strong> procedures and progressiveregistrati<strong>on</strong> fees;2) Supportive investment climate;3) Fair commercial transacti<strong>on</strong>s between in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malenterprises and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal firms;4) Appropriate legal and regulatory frameworks,including en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceable commercialc<strong>on</strong>tracts, private property rights, use266


of public space, tax-funded incentives(including government procurement, taxrebates, tax-funded subsidies, and incentivepackages).• Providing financial, business development, andmarketing services to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal enterprises;• Creating mechanisms and financing arrangementsto provide social protecti<strong>on</strong> to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malentrepreneurs;• Promoting participatory policy processes andinclusive rule-setting instituti<strong>on</strong>s that includerepresentatives of associati<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malentrepreneurs.267


Chapter 4 Endnotes1 A business has been defined as an organisati<strong>on</strong>al entity designedto sell goods and/or services in an ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t to generate profit or a financialreturn. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y can be also be a source of employment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> others — inadditi<strong>on</strong> to the owner and operator - and provide wealth and livelihoodsto the owners as well as the employees. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses andIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises are used interchangeably in this report.2 George A. Aryee: ‘Promoting Productivity and Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> inthe Urban In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector - An Integrated Approach. Report <strong>on</strong> Pilotprojects in Bogota, Dar es Salam and Manila -Summary of activities,less<strong>on</strong>s and recommendati<strong>on</strong>s,’ ILO, 3rd (updated ) editi<strong>on</strong>. Dec 2006ISBN 92-2-110343-9.3 Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy,’ Committee <strong>on</strong>Employment and Social Policy, ILO, March 2007.4 Woolcock M., ‘Some Initial Thoughts <strong>on</strong> Empowering In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses,’ c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to CLEP, June 2007.5 Hyden G., African Politics in Comparative Perspective,Cambridge University Press, New York, 2006.6 Hart, K. (1973) In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal income opportunities and urbanemployment in Ghana. Journal of Modern African Studies, 11, 61-897 Devey, R., Skinner, C,, and Valodia, Imraan. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omyEmployment Data in South Africa: A Critical Analysis,’ Forum 2003Papers, Development Policy Research Unit, School of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics,University of Cape Town, http://www.wiego.org/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/devey%20skinner%20valodia%20In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal%20Ec<strong>on</strong>omy%20employment%20data%20in%20ZA.pdf8 UNU-WIDER. 2006.9 Stiglitz, J. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> Globalizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Penguin Group. UK. 2006.p11.10 Stiglitz, J. Op Cit p11. Even if the targets of the MillenniumDevelopment Goal (MDG) <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> water and sanitati<strong>on</strong> are achieved, therewill still be more than 800 milli<strong>on</strong> people without water and 1.8 billi<strong>on</strong>people without sanitati<strong>on</strong> in 2015.Summary, Human DevelopmentReport 2006. Bey<strong>on</strong>d Scarcity: Power, poverty and the global watercrisis. New York. 2006. p13.11 Sen, A. Development as Freedom. 1999. First Anchor Books, USA.12 A business has been defi ned as an organisati<strong>on</strong>al entitydesigned to sell goods and/or services in an ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t to generate profi tor a fi nancial return. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y can be also be a source of employment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>others — in additi<strong>on</strong> to the owner and operator - and provide wealthand livelihoods to the owners as well as the employees.13 Palmade, V. and Anayiotos, A., Rising In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, Viewpoint 298,World Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong> D.C., August 200514 Xaba, J. Horn, P. and Motala, S. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector in Sub-Saharan Africa’. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing paper <strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy, EmploymentSector, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce, Geneva. 2002. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/employment/infeco/download/ssafrica.pdf, p.315 Charmes, J. (cited at) Women in In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Employment:Globalisati<strong>on</strong> and Organising (WIEGO), 2 nd Annual Meeting, Cambridge,Massachusetts. 22-24 May 2000.16 ‘Parallel Sessi<strong>on</strong> III: Integrated Employment and SocialProtecti<strong>on</strong> Policies to Upgrade the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy,’ 11th AfricanRegi<strong>on</strong>al Meeting, Addis Ababa, 26 April, 2007. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/regi<strong>on</strong>/afpro/addisababa/pdf/in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy.pdf, p.117 Mofokeng, C. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in Africa & Its Impact<strong>on</strong> Women’, Paper presented at the Symposium <strong>on</strong> Women’s Rightsand the Role of Women in Africa, Canada, October 3, 2005. http://canadianlabour.ca/updir/africaenwomen.pdf, p.218 ILO DG report ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Dilemma of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector.’ 1991.19 Mofokeng, C. Op Cit. p.6.20 Gallin, D. ‘Organising in the Global In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy.’Bogazici University Social Policy Forum: Changing Role of Uni<strong>on</strong>s inthe C<strong>on</strong>temporary World of Labour, Istanbul, November 26-27, 2004.http://www.global-abour.org/workers_in_the_in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal_ec<strong>on</strong>omy.htm21 ‘Market Life in West Africa: Markets and the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy.’http://www.khm.uio.no/utstillinger/madeinafrica/english/marked_6.html22 A market is defi ned as a social arrangement that allows buyersand sellers to discover in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and carry out a voluntary exchangeof goods or services. It is c<strong>on</strong>sidered as <strong>on</strong>e of the two key instituti<strong>on</strong>sthat organise trade, al<strong>on</strong>g with the right to own property (Wikipedia).23 Stiglitz, J. Op Cit. Also, nearly 741 milli<strong>on</strong> Indians in ruralareas are poorly served, despite a huge demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fi nancial services,including an estimated annual credit demand exceeding $10 billi<strong>on</strong>.24 Sen, A. Op Cit. p.4-5. Opportunities to satisfy hunger, achievesuffi cient nutriti<strong>on</strong>, enjoy clean water and sanitati<strong>on</strong>, receive basiceducati<strong>on</strong>, health care, etc. are am<strong>on</strong>g the c<strong>on</strong>stitutive comp<strong>on</strong>ents ofdevelopment.25 Discovering Hidden Assets. Financing the Base of the Pyramid.Developing Alternatives. Vol.10, Issue 1. Winter 2005. p4.26 Stiglitz, J. Op Cit.27 Chang, H-J. Str<strong>on</strong>ger than Ficti<strong>on</strong>? Understanding Instituti<strong>on</strong>alChanges and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Development. Policy Brief. UNU-WIDER.Finland. 6 November 2007.28 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> underlying assumpti<strong>on</strong> of many interventi<strong>on</strong>s targetingwomen is that engagement in ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity will translate intoec<strong>on</strong>omic empowerment (Safi lios-Rothschild, 1990; Goetz and SenGupta, 1996). Such assumpti<strong>on</strong>s rest <strong>on</strong> the belief that women securethe benefi ts of their involvement in an ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity. However,research has shown that outcomes vary according to both the type ofactivity and women’s household circumstances.29 Given a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> system, an entrepreneur always decideswhether or not to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malise depending <strong>on</strong> the value of their fi rms.Arruñada, B. Pitfalls to Avoid when Measuring Instituti<strong>on</strong>s: Is DoingBusiness Damaging Business? Pompeu Fabra University. Barcel<strong>on</strong>a. 17June 2007. p15.30 For instance, according to Friedrich Schneider, citizens behaveaccording to a ‘tax morality’, which describes the readiness ofindividuals to leave their offi cial occupati<strong>on</strong>s and enter the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy. If citizens feel that their government is corrupt, they will feelless inclined to cooperate with state rules and regulati<strong>on</strong>s. As such,it is assumed that a declining tax morality increases the size of thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.31 Decent work and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. ILO, 90 th Sessi<strong>on</strong>. 2002.pp.2-332 Recently completed studies of eight countries: Bangladesh,Brazil, Ghana, India, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, Tunisia, Uganda and Vietnam. Cord,Louise . Promoting Pro-Poor Growth: Less<strong>on</strong>s from country experiences.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank. In Analysing and Achieving Pro-Poor Growth. Povertyin Focus. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Poverty Centre. UNDP. March 2007.268


33 Chen, M. Rethinking the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: Linkages with theFormal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy and the Formal Regulatory Envir<strong>on</strong>ment. EGDI andUNU-WIDER C<strong>on</strong>ference ‘Unlocking Human Potential: Linking theFormal and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sectors.’ Helsinki, Finland. 17-18 September 200434 Dar es Salaam In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector Survey. 1995. ILO35 Manushi S. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, Liberty & Livelihood. A bottom up Agenda ofEc<strong>on</strong>omic Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. www.manushi-india.org36 Ishengoma, E. K., Kappel, R.. Formalising In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Firms: Whatcan be d<strong>on</strong>e? In Analysing and Achieving Pro-Poor Growth. Poverty inFocus. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Poverty Centre. UNDP. March 200737 Eneste and Schneider, 1998 and WDI, 2002. Includes 53developed and developing countries from all c<strong>on</strong>tinents exceptAustralia. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> OECD country data is based <strong>on</strong> the average WB reportedGDP per capita at c<strong>on</strong>stant 1995 US$.38 Loyaza, N. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omics of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector; A simple modeland some empirical evidence from Latin America. World Bank PolicyResearch Papers. 199739 Cord, L. Promoting Pro-Poor Growth: Less<strong>on</strong>s from countryexperiences. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank. In Analysing and Achieving Pro-PoorGrowth. Poverty in Focus. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Poverty Centre. UNDP. March200740 This secti<strong>on</strong> was drawn by and largely from ILO, 2002, Op Cit.41 J. Charmes, cited at Women in In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Employment: Globalizingand Organising (WIEGO) Sec<strong>on</strong>d Annual Meeting, Cambridge,Massachusetts, 22-24 May 2000. In ILO, 2002, Op Cit, p.16.42 Op Cit, ILO,p.1643 Carr, M., Chen, M. A.: Globalisati<strong>on</strong> and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy;How global trade and investment impact <strong>on</strong> the working poor,background paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO Report, 2002. May 2001.44 F. Verdera: In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality in Latin America: Recent trends, policiesand prospects. Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO Technical <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>shop <strong>on</strong> Old andNew facets of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, Geneva. 2 March 2001.45 http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/76309/dc2002/proceedings/pdfppt/statistics.pdf46 Nurul Amin, A.T.M. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector in Asia from the decentwork perspective. ILO. 2002.47 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> role of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector through the stages of developmentand cycles of ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Asia Evidence. Paper presentedat the ILO Technical <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>shop <strong>on</strong> Old and New Facets of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality.Geneva. 2 March 2001.48 WIEGO-Women in In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: Globalising and Organising,www.wiego.org49 Lundström, S. and R<strong>on</strong>nås, P., Swedish Internati<strong>on</strong>alDevelopment Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Agency, Sida in Analysing and achieving Pro-Poor Growth. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Poverty Centre, March 2007. Brazil.50 Sangathan, M., Op Cit.51 Ishengoma, E. K., Kappel, R. Formalising In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Firms: Whatcan be d<strong>on</strong>e? March 2007. Op Cit.52 <strong>Legal</strong> Identity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Inclusive Development. ADB. 2007. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Philippines. p.xiv-xv53 While it is estimated that the achievement of water andsanitati<strong>on</strong> related MDG Goals require an additi<strong>on</strong>al annual funding ofUS$10-US$25billi<strong>on</strong>, the scenario would appear distinctively differentand be more manageable if the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to achieve these targets aresupplemented by service delivery through PPPs particularly through theempowerment of the local communities to manage their need througheffective value chain strategies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> same rati<strong>on</strong>ale will apply <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theprovisi<strong>on</strong> of an estimated US$700 billi<strong>on</strong> of investment required tobring electricity to an additi<strong>on</strong>al US$1.4billi<strong>on</strong> people.54 Rodrik, Dani. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Limits of Self En<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing C<strong>on</strong>tracts. Reacti<strong>on</strong>Essay. August 9, 2007.55 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> world’s fastest growing market now, it argues, is at the‘bottom of the pyramid.’ With nearly four billi<strong>on</strong> people living <strong>on</strong>less than US$1500/year, the opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the private sector aresizeable.56 Bannock, G. et al. (2002) Indigenous Private Sector Developmentand Regulati<strong>on</strong> in Africa and Central Europe: A 10 Country Study.L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Bannock C<strong>on</strong>sulting.57 World Bank, Doing Business Report 2003-200658 World Bank, Doing Business Report, 2007.59 USAID, Removing Barriers to Formalisati<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mand Emerging Best Practice, 200560 De Soto, H. 1989. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Other Path (New York: Basic Books)61 Ibid.62 Ibid.63 Building Resources Across Communities (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merly known asBangladesh Rural Advancement Committee)64 ILD paper <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Tools to Empower In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses,submitted in 2006 to our working group <strong>on</strong> Chapter 4.65 De Soto, Hernando. 1989. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Other Path (New York: BasicBooks), and 2000. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Mystery of Capital (New York: Basic Books).66 ILO DGReport ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Dilemma of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector’ 199167 Woolcock M., ‘ Some Initial Thoughts <strong>on</strong> Empowering In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses,’ a note to CLEP <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Group 4, June 2006.68 UN Report <strong>on</strong> Social Development 2005.69 State of the World 2007: Our Urban Future, Worldwatch Institute.70 An estimated 1.6 milli<strong>on</strong> urban residents die each year due tolack of clean water and sanitati<strong>on</strong> as a result. Cities Key to TacklingPoverty, Climate Change, Worldwatch Institute, January 10, 2007.71 Sheehan, M. State of the World 2007 Project Director.‘Policymakers need to address the ‘urbanizati<strong>on</strong> of poverty’ by steppingup investments in educati<strong>on</strong>, healthcare, and infrastructure.’ From1970 to 2000, urban aid worldwide was estimated at US$60 billi<strong>on</strong> —just 4 percent of the US$1.5 trilli<strong>on</strong> in total development assistance.72 A study sp<strong>on</strong>sored by the World Bank in Luanda involved ananalysis of the existing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal water market and the communities’willingness to pay <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> services or participate in the programme in otherways. More than 50 percent of Luanda’s populati<strong>on</strong>, and most who live inthe musseques, do not have access to piped water. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> peri-urban andmusseque populati<strong>on</strong> is <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced to pay extremely high prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> (oftenuntreated) water pumped from the Bengo River and distributed by tankertrucks to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sellers in the various bairros. While the private sectorhas stepped in to provide an essential service that the state has failedto deliver, the costs are very high, because of the extreme inefficiency ofdelivering water to the bairros by tanker truck rather than by pipe. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>study of the water market dem<strong>on</strong>strated that musseque residents wereaccustomed to paying up to 10,000 times more <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> water to the privatesellers than the well-to-do in the cement city were paying <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> treatedwater piped to their household taps by the provincial water company.Ir<strong>on</strong>ically the poor were far more accustomed to pay dearly <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> services269


than the rich. It further dem<strong>on</strong>strated that US$35 milli<strong>on</strong> per year waspaid by the urban poor <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> purchasing water, and that much of thisincome could eventually be recovered in water fees if a just set of tariffswas set at equitable prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all c<strong>on</strong>sumers. Cain, A. Livelihoods and theIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in Post-War Angola. Published in M<strong>on</strong>ograph No. 102,August 2004. Supporting Sustainable Livelihoods-A Critical Review ofAssistance in Post-c<strong>on</strong>flict Situati<strong>on</strong>s. Edited by Clover, J. and Cornwell, R.73 Sachs, J. Capacity-net. E-DISCUSSION: Capacity to effectivelyand sustainably deliver local basic services to the poor. C<strong>on</strong>sider acountry at US$300 per capita. It typically raises around 15 percent ofGNP in tax revenues, or US$45 per capita <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all government services.If it is very well governed, it perhaps devotes 20 percent of the budgetto health, or US$9 per capita per year.74 ILO: A Global Agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Employment: Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper.75 Besley, T., Burgess, R. and Esteve-Volart, B. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Policy Originsof Poverty and Growth in India. In Analysing and Achieving Pro-PoorGrowth. March 2007. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Poverty Centre. UNDP76 Decent work and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. ILO. 2002. p3577 Over the last nearly three decades, micro-fi nance has servednearly 100 milli<strong>on</strong> people in nearly 100 countries.78 For example, commercial banks in Latin America were knownto enter the micro-fi nance markets after a decline in the reserverequirements imposed <strong>on</strong> them from 50percent to about 10-30percentwas introduced.79 ILO. 1999. Central bank of the West African States: Data Bank <strong>on</strong>micro-fi nance instituti<strong>on</strong>s in West African M<strong>on</strong>etary Uni<strong>on</strong>.80 While targeted savings and c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> loans includingRotating Savings and Credit Societies and savings clubs can helpthe poor to cope with day-to-day events, but as risks increase inmagnitude and uncertainty, the losses increase and simple savingsand loan activities are unable to manage those losses. Brown, W. WhyMFIs are providing insurance to low income people? 2000. Dhaka81 Kawas, C. and Gitterman, M. 2000. Roundtable <strong>on</strong> MicroinsuranceServices in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role of Micro-fi nanceInstituti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ford Foundati<strong>on</strong>. New York.82 Cohen, M<strong>on</strong>ique and Jennefer Sebstad. 2003. ReducingVulnerability: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Microinsurance. Microsave-Africa. Nairobi.83 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remittance transfer market is limited; it is dominated by theWestern Uni<strong>on</strong> with Visa and Mastercard having a signifi cant share.84 For instance, currently US$100 remitted to Venezuela translatesinto <strong>on</strong>ly US$50 received by the receiver.85 World Bank Assistance to Agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa:An IEG Review. Independent Evaluati<strong>on</strong> Group. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank.Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC. 200786 Stiglitz, J. Op Cit. Also, nearly 741 milli<strong>on</strong> Indians in ruralareas are poorly served, despite a huge demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fi nancial services,including an estimated annual credit demand exceeding US$10 billi<strong>on</strong>87 Not surprisingly, various reports have been advising the UNto strengthen its relati<strong>on</strong>ship with the private sector <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> M<strong>on</strong>terreyC<strong>on</strong>sensus highlights the necessity to engage the private sectoras a prerequisite <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty alleviati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> report of the UN’s<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> the Private Sector and Development entitled ‘UnleashingEntrepreneurship — <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> Business <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor’ emphasisesimproving the envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> private sector development and privateinvestment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> UN Millennium Project Report urges the private sectorto play a central role in reducing income poverty through inclusive andsustainable ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, while encouraging governments to providethe enabling envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> them to do so. In highlighting the need<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> new partnerships to tackle global challenges and achieve globallyagreed priorities, Report of the Panel of Eminent Pers<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> UnitedNati<strong>on</strong>s-Civil Society relati<strong>on</strong>s, underscores the need to c<strong>on</strong>nect the localwith the Global and the critical role of n<strong>on</strong> state actors including theprivate sector as partners in policy-making and decisi<strong>on</strong>-making.88 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> world’s fastest growing market now, it argues, is at the‘bottom of the pyramid.’ With nearly four billi<strong>on</strong> people living <strong>on</strong> lessthan US$1500/year, the opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the private sector are sizeable.89 Chang, H.-J. Str<strong>on</strong>ger than Ficti<strong>on</strong>? Understanding Instituti<strong>on</strong>alChanges and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Development. Policy Brief. UNU-WIDER.Finland. 6 November 2007.90 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> underlying assumpti<strong>on</strong> of many interventi<strong>on</strong>s targetingwomen is that engagement in ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity will translate intoec<strong>on</strong>omic empowerment (Safi lios-Rothschild, 1990; Goetz and SenGupta, 1996). Such assumpti<strong>on</strong>s rest <strong>on</strong> the belief that women securethe benefi ts of their involvement in an ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity. However,research has shown that outcomes vary according to both the type ofactivity and women’s household circumstances.91 Dickers<strong>on</strong>, C. OHADA countries in Western and Central Africa.92 ILD ‘Best Practices to Empower Business Organisati<strong>on</strong> —Gabriel Daly,’ December 2006.93 Benchmarking the Administrati<strong>on</strong> of Business Start-ups, FinalReport; prepared by CSES <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Enterprise Directorate General of theEuropean <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>; 200294 Hyden G., African Politics in Comparative Perspective,Cambridge University Press, New York, 2006.95 Makerere University Business School, Global EntrepreneurshipM<strong>on</strong>itor: GEM Uganda 2004 Executive Report, the GEM website, 2007.96 Bannock G. and Kapila S., from notes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the draft Sessi<strong>on</strong>alPaper <strong>on</strong> MSEs in Kenya, 2004.97 Hyden G., African Politics.98 Ibid.99 Benito Arruñada ‘Pitfalls to Avoid when Measuring Instituti<strong>on</strong>s:Is Doing Business Damaging Business?’ Dept. of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics andBusiness. Universitat Pompeu Fabra. Trias Fargas, 25. 08005-Barcel<strong>on</strong>a (Spain) June 17, 2007.100 Ibid.101 Scott, J. (1998) Seeing Like a State: How Well-Intenti<strong>on</strong>edSchemes to Improve the Human C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> Have Failed New Haven: YaleUniversity PressPritchett, L. and Woolcock, M. (2004) ‘Soluti<strong>on</strong>s when the Soluti<strong>on</strong> isthe Problem: Arraying the Disarray in Development’ World Development32(2): 191-212.102 Ibid.103 Woolcock, M. (2007) ‘ Notes to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’s In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Group: World Bank.104 Sobhan, R. ‘A Macro Policy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poverty Eradicati<strong>on</strong> throughStructural Change.’ UN University, Wider, January 2005.105 This secti<strong>on</strong> was c<strong>on</strong>tributed by Prof. Rehman Sobhan, op. cit.106 Ibid.107 USAID, 2006270


Chapter 4 BibliographyADB, ‘<strong>Legal</strong> Identity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Inclusive Development’. 2007. Manila,Philippines.Amin, A.T.M. Nurul. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector in Asia from the decent workperspective’. ILO. 2002.Arruñada, Benito. ‘Pitfalls to Avoid When Measuring Instituti<strong>on</strong>s: IsDoing Business Damaging Business?’ Pompeu FabraUniversity. Barcel<strong>on</strong>a. June 2007.Aryee, George A.: ‘Promoting Productivity and Social Protecti<strong>on</strong> in theUrban In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector — An Integrated Approach. Report<strong>on</strong> Pilot projects in Bogota, Dar es Salam and Manila -Summary of activities,less<strong>on</strong>s and recommendati<strong>on</strong>s’ ILO,third (updated ) editi<strong>on</strong> Dec 2006Bannock, G. et al. ‘Indigenous Private Sector Development andRegulati<strong>on</strong> in Africa and Central Europe: A 10 CountryStudy.’ L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>, Bannock C<strong>on</strong>sulting. 2002Besley, Timothy, Robert Burgess and Berta Esteve-Volart. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> PolicyOrigins of Poverty and Growth in India. In Analysing andAchieving Pro-Poor Growth. March 2007. Internati<strong>on</strong>alPoverty Centre. UNDPBrown, Warren. ‘Why MFIs are providing insurance to low incomepeople?’ Dhaka, 2000. Cain, Allan. ‘Livelihoods and theIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in Post-War Angola’. Published inM<strong>on</strong>ograph No. 102, August 2004.Brustinow, Angelika, ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor; AlternativeDispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong>.’ Prepared by, UNECE, 2006.CARE, Canada, ‘Heads or Tails — Extra Nati<strong>on</strong>al Dimensi<strong>on</strong>s ofInternati<strong>on</strong>al Development’ April 2007.______., ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Missing Middle of Investment in Developing Countries’Aril 2007______., ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Story of John and Juan- Social Entrepreneurialism andbarriers to the business <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>’ February 2007Carr, M., M. A. Chen: Globalizati<strong>on</strong> and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy; Howglobal trade and investment impact <strong>on</strong> the working poor,background paper <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO Report, 2002. May 2001Chang, Ha-Jo<strong>on</strong>. ‘Understanding Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Changes and Ec<strong>on</strong>omicDevelopment’ Policy Brief. UNU-WIDER. Finland. 6November 2007.Charmes, Jacques, (cited in) Women in In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Employment:Globalizati<strong>on</strong> and Organising (WIEGO), 2 nd Annual Meeting,Cambridge, Massachusetts. 22-24 May 2000.Chen, Martha ‘Empowerment of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses: <strong>Legal</strong> and otherInterventi<strong>on</strong>s’ Harvard University, Coordinator WIEGO Dec2006______ , ‘<strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms to Empower In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses:Unpacking the Issue,’ Harvard University , Coordinator,WIEGO Dec 2006______., ‘Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Mismatch — Formal Instituti<strong>on</strong>s and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malRealities, May 2007.______., ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malisati<strong>on</strong> of Labour Markets: Is Formalisati<strong>on</strong> theAnswer?’ Harvard University, Coordinator WIEGO.______., ‘Mapping size and diversity of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy’ May 2007.______., ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Business Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy —creating c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>’ November 2005.______.. Rethinking the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: Linkages with the FormalEc<strong>on</strong>omy and the Formal Regulatory Envir<strong>on</strong>ment. EGDIand UNU-WIDER C<strong>on</strong>ference ‘Unlocking Human Potential:Linking the Formal and In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sectors.’ Helsinki, Finland.Sept. 2004Cohen, M<strong>on</strong>ique and Jennefer Sebstad. Reducing Vulnerability: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Microinsurance. Microsave-Africa. Nairobi.C<strong>on</strong>sultative Group <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor (CGAP), World Bank, ‘Safe and Accessible:Bringing poor saver into <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal fi nancial system’September 2006.Cord, Louise. Promoting Pro-Poor Growth: Less<strong>on</strong>s from countryexperiences. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank. In Analysing and AchievingPro-Poor Growth. Poverty in Focus. Internati<strong>on</strong>al PovertyCentre. UNDP. March 2007Crecentia, Mofokeng. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in Africa & Its Impact <strong>on</strong>Women,’ Paper presented at the Symposium <strong>on</strong> Women’sRights and the Role of Women in Africa, Canada, October3, 2005Dayaratna-Banda, O. G., ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Trade in Sri Lanka,’ Departmentof Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Statistics, Faculty of Arts, University ofPeradeniya, Peradeniya, 20400, Sri Lanka, Nov.2006.De Soto, Hernando. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Other Path (New York: Basic Books), 1989 and .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Mystery of Capital (New York: Basic Books) 2000.Devey, Richard, Skinner, Caroline, and Valodia, Imraan. ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy Employment Data in South Africa: A CriticalAnalysis,’ Forum Papers, Development Policy Research Unit,School of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, University of Cape Town, 2003Discovering Hidden Assets-Financing the Base of the Pyramid.Developing Alternatives. Vol.10, Issue 1. Winter 2005.Djankov, Sime<strong>on</strong>, Ira Lieberman, Joyita Mukherjee, and Tatiana Nenova,‘Going In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal: Benefi ts and Costs,’ World Bank, 2002FIAS/World Bank Group-ISSER, ‘Regi<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> EnterpriseFormalisati<strong>on</strong> in Africa,’ Accra, Ghana, January 10-11,2007Gallin, Dan. ‘Organising in the Global In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy’, BogaziciUniversity Social Policy Forum: Changing Role of Uni<strong>on</strong>sin the C<strong>on</strong>temporary World of Labor, Istanbul, November26-27, 2004.Golub, Stephen, ‘Bey<strong>on</strong>d Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Orthodoxy — <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment Alternative,’ Carnegie Endowment, October2003.Government of India ‘Report <strong>on</strong> Social Security <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Unorganised<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers,’ prepared by the Nati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector, Government of India.May 2006.Hart, K. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal income opportunities and urban employment inGhana. Journal of Modern African Studies, 1973.Hyden G., African Politics in Comparative Perspective, CambridgeUniversity Press, New York, 2006.ILO, DG report ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Dilemma of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector’ 1991______., Dar es Salaam In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector Survey. 1995.______. Central bank of the West African States: Data Bank <strong>on</strong> microfinance instituti<strong>on</strong>s in West African M<strong>on</strong>etary Uni<strong>on</strong>, 1999______., Decent work and the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. , 90 th Sessi<strong>on</strong>. 2002271


______., ‘Ghana Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pilot Programme- Ghana <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Out ofPoverty’, January 2006.______., Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy’, Committee <strong>on</strong>Employment and Social Policy, March 2007______.: A Global Agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Employment: Discussi<strong>on</strong> PaperILO, UNIDO, UNDP ‘Roadmap Study of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector in mainlandTanzania’, 2002.Ind<strong>on</strong>, Reginald ‘<strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms to Empower In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Businesses-Philippines Experience,’ February 2007Ishengoma, Esther K and Robert Kappel, ‘Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth andPoverty: Does Formalisati<strong>on</strong> of In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Enterprises Matter,’German institute of Global and Area Studies, April 2006______., Formalising In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Firms: What can be d<strong>on</strong>e? In Analysingand Achieving Pro-Poor Growth. Poverty in Focus.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Poverty Centre. UNDP. March 2007Kapila, Sunita, ‘Unleashing the Entrepreneurial Potential of Microand Small Businesses in Kenya: Some Experiences andDirecti<strong>on</strong>s,’ Nairobi, October 2006.Karunagoda, Nanda, ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Markets <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Financial Services in SriLanka,’ Sri Lanka, Aug.2006Kashyap, Arun, ‘Business Rights - Outline and Framework,’ UNDP, July-October 2007.Kawas, Celina and Marla Gitterman. Roundtable <strong>on</strong> MicroinsuranceServices in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role of Micro-fi nanceInstituti<strong>on</strong>s .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ford Foundati<strong>on</strong>. New York. 2000Keny<strong>on</strong>, Thomas and Emers<strong>on</strong> Kapaz, ‘In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality Trap’ Public Policy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Private Sector, World Bank, Dec 2005.Kuchta-Helbling, Catherine ‘Background Paper — Barriers toparticipati<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector in emerging democracies’<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Movement <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Democracy, Sao Paulo, Brazil, 2000Lex Mundi Pro B<strong>on</strong>o Foundati<strong>on</strong> ‘Technical Papers from Bangladesh,Thailand, Philippines, Mexico, Bolivia, Peru, South Africa,Sri Lanka’Loyaza, Norman. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omics of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector; A simple modeland some empirical evidence from Latin America. WorldBank Policy Research Papers. 1997Loayza, N. and Jamele Rigolini,’ In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality Trends and Cycles’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>World Bank, 2005Lundström, Susanna and Per R<strong>on</strong>nås, Swedish Internati<strong>on</strong>alDevelopment Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Agency, Sida in ‘Analysing andachieving Pro-Poor Growth.’ Internati<strong>on</strong>al Poverty Centre,Brazil, March 2007.Moore Dickers<strong>on</strong>, Claire, ‘Harm<strong>on</strong>izing Business <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in Africa’ OHADA,2005______., ‘<strong>Legal</strong> Mechanisms to empower in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses— suggested outline and notes’ June 2007.Musiolek Bettina, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper <strong>on</strong> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy ‘Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector: Central and Eastern Europe / andComm<strong>on</strong> Wealth of Independent States and other <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merSoviet Republics,’ ILO. 2002.Nicholas, Stephen and Elizabeth Maitland, ‘How business interactswith in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s,’ OECD, 2005Ocici, Charles, ‘Entrepreneurship- Ugandan Experience’, Internati<strong>on</strong>al<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Institute, Ugandan, African Centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong>Excellence, Kampala Uganda, November 2006.Olomi,. D<strong>on</strong>ath R.,’Unleashing Entrepreneurial Potentials of the Poorin Tanzania: Prospects, Challenges and Way Forward.’University of Dar es Salaam Entrepreneurship Centre(UDEC), Dar-e- Salaam, Tanzania, November 2006.Palmade, Vincent and Andrea Anayiotos, Rising In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, Viewpoint298, World Bank, Washingt<strong>on</strong> D.C., August 2005Pasquel, Enrique, ‘<strong>Legal</strong> Tools to Empower Business Organisati<strong>on</strong>s- A New Approach to Formalisati<strong>on</strong>’ prepared by ILD, Lima,Peru, December, 2006Daly, Gabriel ‘Best Practices to Empower Business Organisati<strong>on</strong>sprepared by, ILD, Lima, Peru, Dec 2006.Khoudeir, Ayman H. R.: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector Impacts <strong>on</strong> theEnvir<strong>on</strong>ment- In Reference to Egypt prepared by of SocialFund, Cairo, Egypt. Dec 2006Pritchett, Lant and Michael Woolcock, ‘Soluti<strong>on</strong>s when the Soluti<strong>on</strong> isthe Problem: Arraying the Disarray in Development’ WorldDevelopment 32(2): 2004Sangathan, Manushi. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, Liberty & Livelihood. A bottom up Agendaof Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. www.manushi-india.orgSarvananthan, Muttukrishna’In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in the C<strong>on</strong>fl ict AffectedRegi<strong>on</strong> of Sri Lanka: An Explorati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pathfi nderFoundati<strong>on</strong>, Colombo, Sri Lanka. August 2006.Scott, James ‘Seeing Like a State: How Well-Intenti<strong>on</strong>ed Schemes toImprove the Human C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> Have Failed ‘ New Haven:Yale University Press1998.Sen, Amartya. ‘Development as Freedom’. First Anchor Books, USA.1999SEWA ‘ Public Private Partnership in Agriculture — SEWA’s experienceand Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s, SEWA, Ahmedabad, India.November 2006.SEWA, ‘Self-employed Women’s Associati<strong>on</strong> Trade Facilitati<strong>on</strong> Centre(SFTC) — An Overview,’ Prepared by SEWA, Ahmedabad,India.Sobhan, Rehman ‘A Macro Policy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poverty Eradicati<strong>on</strong> throughStructural Change,’ UN University, Wider, January 2005State of the World: ‘Our Urban Future,’ Worldwatch Institute. 2007Stiglitz, Joseph. ‘Bey<strong>on</strong>d Scarcity: Power. Poverty and the global watercrisis.’ New York. 2006.______.. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> Globalizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>’. Penguin Group. UK. 2006.UN Report <strong>on</strong> Social Development 2005UNDP, ‘Growing Inclusive Markets: Business <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>s fro Development,Development works <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Business,’ June 2007UNDP, ‘Unleashing Entrepreneurship, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> Business <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thePoor,’ March 2004.United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Expert Group <strong>on</strong> Women and Finance, Women’s WorldBanking, 1994USAID, Removing Barriers to Formalisati<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m andEmerging Best Practice, 2005______. ‘Land and Business Formalisati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor’ Nov, 2006.Verdera, F. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality in Latin America: Recent trends, policies andprospects. Paper prepared <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO Technical <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>shop <strong>on</strong>Old and New facets of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality, Geneva. March 2001.272


WIEGO, ‘Accra Hawkers Associati<strong>on</strong>,’ News from Ghana Daily Graphic,May 2006,WIEGO Women in In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: Globalising and Organising, www.wiego.orgWomen’s World Banking, ‘Banking <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Majority: Profi table andResp<strong>on</strong>sible Micro Finance,’ Federati<strong>on</strong> of Latin AmericanBanks and Women’s World Banking. 1994.Women’s World Banking, Client Case Studies from the DominicanRepublic, Bank ADOPEM, Women’s World Banking, NewYork, USA, www.swwb.orgWoolcock M., ‘Some Initial Thoughts <strong>on</strong> Empowering In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malBusinesses,’ World Bank notes to CLEP, June 2007.World Bank ‘Doing Business 2007 — How to Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m’, September 2006.______. ‘Rural Investment Climate Survey: Ind<strong>on</strong>esia,’ September2006.______., Doing Business Report 2003-2006Xaba, Jantjie, Horn, Pat, and Motala, Shirin. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sectorin Sub-Saharan Africa.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing paper <strong>on</strong> the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy, Employment Sector, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Offi ce,Geneva. 2002.273


ChapterFIVERoad Maps <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Implementati<strong>on</strong>of Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msImplementati<strong>on</strong> Strategies,Including Toolkits and Indices275


EXECUTIVE SUMMARYExisting power structures prevent poor people from taking charge of their lives and occupati<strong>on</strong>s andachieving upward mobility. To end poverty, those structures must be reorganised — a challenging task dueto the many dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of poverty and disempowerment. Interchangeable soluti<strong>on</strong>s do not work acrosscountries in exactly the same ways; practiti<strong>on</strong>ers must be inventive and experimental to produce more justrelati<strong>on</strong>ships am<strong>on</strong>g the state, the marketplace and the poor.Listening to the poor and learning by doingare critically important. Civil societies,n<strong>on</strong>-governmental organisati<strong>on</strong>s, membership-basedgroups of employers and of workers,coaliti<strong>on</strong>s and networks have major roles to play ingenerating and articulating bottom-up demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legal empowerment. Support of central authoritiesis also vital <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sustaining progress in most countries.Policy champi<strong>on</strong>s are needed to bring othergovernment actors <strong>on</strong> board to preclude policyspoilers from blocking implementati<strong>on</strong> of legalempowerment.Implementati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor(<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor) in a countrybegins with c<strong>on</strong>textual analysis, focusing <strong>on</strong> thesocial and cultural features that could affectimplementati<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> must also be givento the ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>text (which can be both a helpand a hindrance), and to the openness and capacityof the state. Supplementing the inventory ofthese c<strong>on</strong>cerns should be a careful analysis of thereach and hold that in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s have <strong>on</strong>the poor. A full c<strong>on</strong>textual analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms the basis<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a feasibility review of various empowermentscenarios.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most important c<strong>on</strong>straints set by the nati<strong>on</strong>alsocio-political c<strong>on</strong>text are:• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> domestic social structure, especially its gender,class and ethnic makeup, as well as culturalattitudes toward participati<strong>on</strong> and equality;• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>text — including the distributi<strong>on</strong>of wealth and income, and the level and rateof ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth;• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> characteristics of the state — both the politicaland the administrative system;• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> extent of ec<strong>on</strong>omic and political in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malityand tensi<strong>on</strong>s with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and officially recognisedsystems.Practiti<strong>on</strong>ers and policymakers can use the tool ofc<strong>on</strong>textual analysis within a country to determine:1) if c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s appear ripe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms; 2) which implementati<strong>on</strong> opti<strong>on</strong>s seemmost probable; 3) what sequencing and timelines<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m look doable; 4) how the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms shouldbe designed; 5) what tradeoffs need to be c<strong>on</strong>sidered;6) which risk-mitigating mechanisms areworth trying, and 7) what c<strong>on</strong>textual variables needcareful m<strong>on</strong>itoring during implementati<strong>on</strong>.276


Following the c<strong>on</strong>textual analysis — or perhapssimultaneously with it since implementati<strong>on</strong> stepsare never discrete — local activists and externalchange agents should undertake a stakeholderanalysis of the c<strong>on</strong>stituencies c<strong>on</strong>cerned with <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> objective is to differentiateam<strong>on</strong>g the superficially homogeneousbeneficiaries, to better understand the divisi<strong>on</strong>s,alliances and particular needs that exist am<strong>on</strong>gthe poor. Other stakeholders who might opposeor assist the target group or groups also need tobe scrutinised to see what motivates their behaviourand to reflect <strong>on</strong> how they could be broughtinto the process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> purpose of the stakeholderanalysis is to get a firmer grasp of the probabilityof moving <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward with various legal empowermentalternatives, and to begin serious thinking aboutwhat it might take to build a minimum winningcoaliti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment in the country.Stakeholders act out of regard <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their own advantage,as they define it. Poor people are the targetbeneficiaries of legal empowerment and need tohave as big a hand as possible in initiating anddesigning the relevant policies. Even though theylack physical, financial or organisati<strong>on</strong>al resources,and even social capital in many locales, the pooralways have a passive capacity to derail legalre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms aimed at them. Because poor stakeholdersare diverse, legal empowerment policies may havesurprisingly uneven impact if officials are inattentiveto the needs and preferences of the intendedbeneficiaries.<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment also creates policy ‘losers’,no matter what the broader merits are. It oftenredistributes a right or benefit from <strong>on</strong>e group ofstakeholders to another, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example when thereare mutually exclusive claims to a fixed resourcesuch as fertile land or minerals. Policymakers mayendeavour to minimise redistributive c<strong>on</strong>flicts byexpanding ec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities so that differentinterests can be negotiated to meet every side’sneeds, but plenty of potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong>remains because important stakeholders believeothers’ gains come at their expense. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mutualpayoff to legal empowerment is in the future, butthe individual sacrifices must be borne now.Finally (though again the chr<strong>on</strong>ology wouldprobably be overlapping), the internal technicalfeatures of the alternative courses of acti<strong>on</strong> mustbe reviewed. Policy characteristics analysis wouldfocus <strong>on</strong> the complexities of the different policies,their ambiguity, and their potential to sow discord— all of which may hinder implementati<strong>on</strong>. Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tswould be made to find a simple, incremental, andsustainable way <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward, and to avoid as muchas possible taking steps that provoke needlessc<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong>.Obviously, what legally empowers the poor in <strong>on</strong>enati<strong>on</strong> may be unsuitable in another country, wherethere would likely be a different social structure,ec<strong>on</strong>omic envir<strong>on</strong>ment and universe of stakeholdergroups. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> procedures in determining a suitablere<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m strategy might look alike in both countries,but the substance of the outcome would be sharplydifferent. And in all cases, the process is messyand imprecise, yielding <strong>on</strong>ly what appear to be thebest fitting policies, given the imperfect in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>available to policymakers at the time andunder the political realities.Development professi<strong>on</strong>als must creatively seekto capitalise <strong>on</strong> the specific situati<strong>on</strong> at hand,placing fr<strong>on</strong>t and centre poor people’s percepti<strong>on</strong>s.While legal or organisati<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms may appearself-evidently empowering to outside experts, theyshould be cauti<strong>on</strong>ed that a poor community mightsee them as dangerous from their own perspective.It may be best to move <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward selectively and notdissipate energy <strong>on</strong> too many legal or regulatoryinitiatives at <strong>on</strong>ce. Empowerment policies seldom277


take effect quickly. Individual uncertainty aboutimplementati<strong>on</strong> encourages poor people to withholdsupport <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, which can create self-fulfillingprophecies of slippage. One should there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>elook <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> interventi<strong>on</strong>s promising short-term rewards<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> beneficiaries. Design simplicity should be a keyc<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> to minimise c<strong>on</strong>flict, uncertainty, andother implementati<strong>on</strong> problems arising from theprocedural and technical traits of legal empowermentactivities.Roadmaps to Implementati<strong>on</strong>Effective implementati<strong>on</strong> of policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m takesa mix of experience, professi<strong>on</strong>al judgment, andwillingness to take chances. Creative policymakerslook to open up policy windows that create thespace needed to move <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward in solving particularproblems even under difficult circumstances.Six comm<strong>on</strong> sets of tasks are associated withdeveloping specific nati<strong>on</strong>al roadmaps <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y follow a generalized(but not lockstep) pattern, c<strong>on</strong>ceived as aninteractive cycle launched by a stream of issues,agendas and decisi<strong>on</strong>s that, over time, provide additi<strong>on</strong>alinput and momentum to the process.• Issues, Agendas, and Decisi<strong>on</strong>s: Advocate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>change, develop policy issues, and make decisi<strong>on</strong>sto launch policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Although politiciansand interest groups tend to take the lead,they will seldom succeed without pressure frombelow, and mobilisati<strong>on</strong> from am<strong>on</strong>g the poorthemselves, including their demands.• Policy Formulati<strong>on</strong> and Legitimisati<strong>on</strong>: Addressthe technical c<strong>on</strong>tent of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m measures. However,besides technical c<strong>on</strong>tent, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m measuresneed to be accepted and be seen as necessaryand important. Through their representatives, thepoor should be part of the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m design process.• C<strong>on</strong>stituency Building: C<strong>on</strong>vince beneficiaries ofthe advantages of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, and dem<strong>on</strong>strate thatl<strong>on</strong>g-term benefits are worth short-term costs.• Resource Mobilisati<strong>on</strong>: Ensure the flow of adequateresources by addressing incentives, andexercising leadership in galvanizing c<strong>on</strong>stituencies.Financial, technical, and human resourcecommitments are needed.• Implementati<strong>on</strong> Design and Organisati<strong>on</strong>al Development:Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers need to create and nurturenetworks and partnerships <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> cooperati<strong>on</strong> andcoordinati<strong>on</strong>, and provide <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the developmentof new organisati<strong>on</strong>al skills and capacities in thepublic, private and n<strong>on</strong>-governmental sectors.Old procedures, operating routines, and communicati<strong>on</strong>patterns are difficult to root out; changeis likely to be resisted within some quarters.• Acti<strong>on</strong> Planning and Progress M<strong>on</strong>itoring: Set upsystems and procedures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> obtaining feedbackso that implementati<strong>on</strong> is related to learning andadaptati<strong>on</strong>, so as to produce results and impact.<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor may be perceivedas a spectrum that provides opportunities, protecti<strong>on</strong>and security to beneficiaries. It establishes aminimum ‘floor’ of entitlements and safeguardsto which every<strong>on</strong>e is entitled, by the simple factof our comm<strong>on</strong> humanity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> task is to establishthis floor using human rights law. For every facetof empowerment, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, <strong>on</strong>e test is to identifya range of potential policy opti<strong>on</strong>s from which nati<strong>on</strong>sand citizens can choose, depending <strong>on</strong> theirnati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text and the different starting points ofvarious groups of the poor within them. Finally, aspectrum approach explicitly recognises the incrementalmanner in which poor people improve theirlives in practice.Implementati<strong>on</strong> of empowering policies at thenati<strong>on</strong>al level should seek to integrate legalempowerment into existing processes, such asthe preparati<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al development plans orpoverty reducti<strong>on</strong> strategies, rather than seek to278


establish a ‘legal empowerment programme’ as astand-al<strong>on</strong>e entity. Another important dimensi<strong>on</strong> ofnati<strong>on</strong>al level work will involve working closely withprofessi<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>s to create a new cadre oflegal, engineering or other para-professi<strong>on</strong>als toassist poor men and women.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> base organisati<strong>on</strong> of the poor must be engagedin the design of interventi<strong>on</strong>s of any kind. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>disseminati<strong>on</strong> will be a central strategy<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment at the local level. In somecountries with particularly weak or oppressivenati<strong>on</strong>al governments, community empowermentactivities may be the <strong>on</strong>ly feasible <strong>on</strong>es. Wheresocial mobilisati<strong>on</strong> is str<strong>on</strong>g, however, the legalempowerment agenda can be built, bottom-up, bysupporting existing initiatives of the urban or ruralpoor.Mapping <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment bey<strong>on</strong>dthe Nati<strong>on</strong> StateImplementati<strong>on</strong> undertaken at the global levelshould support country-level activities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> importantdifferences am<strong>on</strong>g countries and regi<strong>on</strong>s call<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a flexible, demand-driven approach that is appropriateto local realities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> likely focus wouldbe <strong>on</strong> two types of measures to encourage legalempowerment at the country level: advocacy andknowledge management. Advocacy activities wouldfocus <strong>on</strong> getting key messages out to importanttarget audiences through a variety of vehicles. Awebsite, or a ‘brand/logo’ that can be added toexisting websites, providing updates and progressreports <strong>on</strong> how the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor agenda is being implemented. An inventoryof evidence <strong>on</strong> capacity development in domainssimilar to <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor wouldbe compiled, and dialogue would be supported todisseminate global good practices.Knowledge management activities should build<strong>on</strong> the initial inventories of good practice, <strong>on</strong>-goinginitiatives and actors engaged in promotingempowerment. A key element is to identify existingindicators and m<strong>on</strong>itoring ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts that would furtherthe <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor agenda. Similarly,and particularly in the case of the rights tojustice and asset holding, evaluati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> learningwill prove to be valuable.In additi<strong>on</strong>, a range of measures should be undertakento prepare <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> country-level dealings. Countriesand internati<strong>on</strong>al support organisati<strong>on</strong>s canbe identified to support the process of change atthe country level. Pro-poor toolkits and methods tosupport capacity building can be inventoried andgaps identified. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se would be made availablethrough a variety of avenues, including websitesand workshops, am<strong>on</strong>g others.At the regi<strong>on</strong>al and sub-regi<strong>on</strong>al levels, activitiesshould also likely focus <strong>on</strong> advocacy and knowledgemanagement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> regi<strong>on</strong> and sub-regi<strong>on</strong> arecritical <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> success of the legal empowerment agenda;at these levels global norms can be adaptedto different socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>texts. Buildingpolitical will <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change will occur through regi<strong>on</strong>aland sub-regi<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s, UN Regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>s,sub-regi<strong>on</strong>al bodies, and in partnershipwith regi<strong>on</strong>al development banks. A series of new‘Regi<strong>on</strong>al Social C<strong>on</strong>tracts’ could be an importantmechanism to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ge political c<strong>on</strong>sensus <strong>on</strong> thelegal empowerment agenda.Toolkits and IndicesCarrying out <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor takesa variety of different tools or specific techniques,many of which have been developed by anti-povertyworkers, community organisers and re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m advocatesaround the world. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se techniques weredesigned to promote activities analogous to thepoor pers<strong>on</strong>’s empowerment agenda of the poor,and they include: advocacy/lobbying; collecti<strong>on</strong> anddisseminati<strong>on</strong> of best practices; community map-279


ping; competencies assessment; c<strong>on</strong>flict preventi<strong>on</strong>and resoluti<strong>on</strong>; domestic resource mobilisati<strong>on</strong>;exchanges; focus groups; <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce field analysis; genderauditing; impact evaluati<strong>on</strong>; influence mapping;instituti<strong>on</strong>al analysis; instituti<strong>on</strong>al twinning; internshipprogrammes; the logical framework approach;nati<strong>on</strong>al symposia; opportunity ranking; mediaoutreach, public hearings and study circles; participatorybudgeting; participatory poverty assessments;translating laws into plain language; political mapping;political will and risk analysis; problem solvingstudies; problem tree analysis; social impact andopportunities assessment; stakeholder m<strong>on</strong>itoringwith household surveys and key in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mant interviews;strategic planning framework; technical assistanceand training <strong>on</strong> leadership, group work, andrelated management issues; travel grants/internships<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> officials; web-based support; and workshops.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se tools are general, flexible and easy tomodify; development practiti<strong>on</strong>ers shouldreject the <strong>on</strong>es that d<strong>on</strong>’t apply to their particularcountry c<strong>on</strong>text. Critical tasks often include thefollowing:• Mobilising stakeholders: Identify key stakeholdersand agree <strong>on</strong> a process as well as a set ofprinciples that will guide the legal empowermentagenda. This should help to build c<strong>on</strong>fidenceam<strong>on</strong>g stakeholders. Key issues include coordinati<strong>on</strong>mechanisms, adopti<strong>on</strong> of a protocol oragreement, clarificati<strong>on</strong> of roles and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities,and agreement <strong>on</strong> a broad process <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.• Situati<strong>on</strong> analysis or legal empowerment diagnostic:A detailed assessment should be made ofthe relevant issues to be addressed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> analysiswill identify policy, legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>cerns,as well as gaps in resources, capacity andtools.• Acti<strong>on</strong> planning: Development of the goal, objectives,strategies, and specific interventi<strong>on</strong>s thatc<strong>on</strong>tribute to the legal empowerment objective.Critical issues include sequencing and timing,resource c<strong>on</strong>straints, establishing a m<strong>on</strong>itoringand evaluati<strong>on</strong> framework, and ensuring a balancebetween process and products required tomaintain momentum.• Pilot activities: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se should be built around theidea of ‘quick wins’ in areas where these are feasible.In this way <strong>on</strong>e can build the credibility ofthe legal empowerment agenda and dem<strong>on</strong>strateinitial success.• Scaling-up: Expanding the range of activities andtaking <strong>on</strong> more complicated challenges. Raisingawareness of past successes, additi<strong>on</strong>al sensitisati<strong>on</strong>,and strengthening the c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> process.• Instituti<strong>on</strong>alising change and the change process:Tackling some of the fundamental re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msby building <strong>on</strong> experiences in the pilot phase andscaling-up phase to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the organisati<strong>on</strong>s andrules that shape the instituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text.Both the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong> and m<strong>on</strong>itoring phases ofimplementati<strong>on</strong> look to indicators of democratisati<strong>on</strong>,good governance, human rights protecti<strong>on</strong>,and many other variables related to legal empowerment.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are numerous measures of differentaspects of governance in the public domain, butun<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tunately, n<strong>on</strong>e is sufficiently developed to beof great value in measuring changes in the politicalor legal status of a country’s poor men and womenover time. Accordingly, legal empowerment programmesand projects must develop and use theirown metrics <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> evaluating the socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omicenvir<strong>on</strong>ment and gauging accomplishments, based<strong>on</strong> surveys and interviews.Acti<strong>on</strong> planning and progress m<strong>on</strong>itoring are especiallyimportant <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> outside agencies. Am<strong>on</strong>g itstools are:• A management in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> system based <strong>on</strong>280


targeted indicators endorsed by nati<strong>on</strong>al stakeholders;• Stakeholder m<strong>on</strong>itoring to identify the resp<strong>on</strong>sesof those that benefited or those that lost fromthe policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m measures;• Problem-solving studies to devise tailored andpractical soluti<strong>on</strong>s to implementati<strong>on</strong> issues;• Process and impact evaluati<strong>on</strong>s to support learningover time.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> design of each comp<strong>on</strong>ent should respectsome important principles: adaptati<strong>on</strong> to userneeds and availability of resources; user participati<strong>on</strong>;parsim<strong>on</strong>y (the least amount of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>and cost required to accomplish the task), andsimplicity. M<strong>on</strong>itoring of the implementati<strong>on</strong> policyre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process will loom large over time, and anumber of practical suggesti<strong>on</strong>s that have beengleaned from less<strong>on</strong>s learned from country experiencesare offered here:• Define a list of steps, processes, targets andmilest<strong>on</strong>e events in the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process. This willenable the breakdown of the policy processesinto a series of comp<strong>on</strong>ents to enable an easiergrasp of what needs to be m<strong>on</strong>itored.• Make use of qualitative rather than quantitativeapproaches in m<strong>on</strong>itoring the system, as theyoffer a more complete and nuanced set of datathat are numeric and narrative.• Engage implementing parties and beneficiariesin drawing up the m<strong>on</strong>itoring systems and methodologiesand acquire feedback. This will simplifythe process of tracking previously identifiedindicators. Focus group discussi<strong>on</strong>s, workshopsand other similar methods can be used to ensureparticipati<strong>on</strong>.• Customise the choice of m<strong>on</strong>itoring methods tothe needs and c<strong>on</strong>straints of the implementingagencies.• Delegate the m<strong>on</strong>itoring process to an externalbody, such as civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s, thinktanks and advocacy groups, to ensure greaterindependence, transparency and accountability.Strategy and TacticsChange agents must put aside prec<strong>on</strong>ceived oruni<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m approaches to empowering the poor andthink creatively about how to make policies available,af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable and acceptable. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> following corevalues bel<strong>on</strong>g fr<strong>on</strong>t and centre:• Poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> is the ultimate objective, soevery re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m must be judged by the extent towhich it imparts the freedom that allows poorpeople to gain more c<strong>on</strong>trol over their futuresand to improve their well-being.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> peaceful struggle against impoverishmentmust be participatory and based <strong>on</strong> respect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>human rights, with the poor playing active rolesal<strong>on</strong>g the way.• Gains of legal empowerment should be broadbasedand take into account the diversity ofdisadvantaged groups, especially indigenouspeople who are often inadvertently overlooked bypolicymakers.• Gains also must include women, hence anotherstandard against which to measure <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor policy is whether it takesfull account of gender-specific effects.• Empowerment of the poor in the end meanssocial trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> — not <strong>on</strong>ly a more justdistributi<strong>on</strong> of wealth and income, but a moreexpansive sharing of power that enables disadvantagedpeople to begin bringing about significantchange through their own acti<strong>on</strong>s.Anumber of strategic opti<strong>on</strong>s and c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>sstand out. Although they are rich withparadox, it will be up to government officials, civilsocietymembers, and development practiti<strong>on</strong>ers to281


sort out the c<strong>on</strong>flicting elements and determine themost promising strategic directi<strong>on</strong> to take <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> theircommunity, their country or their regi<strong>on</strong>. We listthem as follows:• <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor is easiest toimplement where it is needed least.• A rich base of comparative internati<strong>on</strong>al experienceexist, but there are no ready-made <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulas<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment.• Think systemically, act incrementally.• Think l<strong>on</strong>g, go short.• Start from afar, but change from within.• Support associati<strong>on</strong>s of the poor, but do notcompromise their independence.• Bundle service delivery.• Support Alternative Dispute Resoluti<strong>on</strong>.• Collaborate with professi<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s.Change agents may c<strong>on</strong>sider employing these suggesti<strong>on</strong>s.While remaining true to the core valuesof the legal empowerment agenda, they may makeit possible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> many more poor people to improvetheir lives in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eseeable future. Of course,these agents must be prepared to come up againstcountervailing factors, and there can be no guaranteeof successful implementati<strong>on</strong>; but steady andmodest progress in fighting poverty with legal toolsand rights is well within the realm of possibility inmost countries.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> from the bottom up and the top down.• Decentralise — except when it is better to centralise.• Balance demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change with the capacity toaccommodate change.• Put together in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s.• Look <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> cooperati<strong>on</strong>, but anticipate c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong>.While walking the tightrope of these strategic suggesti<strong>on</strong>s,change agents can call up<strong>on</strong> a variety ofimplementati<strong>on</strong> tactics they can use, including:• Be opportunistic.• Use plain and local language.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> with para-professi<strong>on</strong>als.• Bring existing technical soluti<strong>on</strong>s up to date.• Bring together technical expertise and grassrootsexperience.• Dedicate resources to support participatory processesand coordinati<strong>on</strong>.• Provide effective outreach.• Provide access to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.282


1. Introducti<strong>on</strong>: Attributesof <strong>Legal</strong> EmpowermentA singularly promising means <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowering poorpeople, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>tends, is to establishlawful claims they can use to lift themselves outof poverty. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> four interdependent domains ofempowerment highlighted by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> are acoherent, accessible legal order; more secure rightsto assets and possessi<strong>on</strong>s; str<strong>on</strong>ger and clearerlabour rights; and fairer, more c<strong>on</strong>structive rules <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>small business and micro-enterprise. Each domainis meant to provide defences against exploitati<strong>on</strong>and loss of assets; they fit together in a way thatwould work to emancipate the poor to become bothmore productive and better able to keep the surplusesthey produce.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>ceptual framework is depicted graphicallyin Figure 5.1. Due to insecure land tenure systems,and to the unequal distributi<strong>on</strong> of other factors ofproducti<strong>on</strong>, as well as of ec<strong>on</strong>omic and politicalpower, the poor are shut out from ec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities.Voice, identity and assets are the key enablingc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that offer space and leverage tothe poor to bring their legal rights to bear in changingtheir socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic status. Using voice andtaking <strong>on</strong> str<strong>on</strong>ger identity require both bottom-upand top-down instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Membershipbasedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s must be built and strengthened,and state policymaking instituti<strong>on</strong>s must bemade more inclusive and accountable to the poor.Strengthened by voice and identity in their rolesas citizens, asset holders, workers, and entrepreneurs,the poor can begin to use their rights inthe corresp<strong>on</strong>ding empowerment domains to keephold of and grow the resources at their disposal. Ifthings go by design, instituti<strong>on</strong>al restructuring andlegal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m will furnish society’s least advantagedmembers with the capability to raise their stature,meet their basic needs, and eventually move intothe ec<strong>on</strong>omic mainstream. Figure 5.1 also showsthat the link between the enabling c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s andempowerment goes in two directi<strong>on</strong>s, and that thelegal setting both shapes and reflects power relati<strong>on</strong>s.Existing political, administrative and juridicalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s have not been fashi<strong>on</strong>ed with therights of the poor in mind as a major c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>,Figure 5.1 <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the PoorEnabling C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s Empowerment Domains GoalsVoiceOrganizati<strong>on</strong>Representati<strong>on</strong>Instituti<strong>on</strong>alRe<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m+}Identity& AssetsCitizensAsset Holders<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ersEntrepeneurs+<strong>Legal</strong>Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mExerciseof RightsJusticePropertyLabourBusinessProtecti<strong>on</strong>Ec<strong>on</strong>omicOpportunities<strong>Legal</strong>EmpowermentImproved Living Standards283


so the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> is advocating radical changesin the existing distributi<strong>on</strong> of public (and private)power. As the poor gain income, assets and power,they will be in a str<strong>on</strong>ger positi<strong>on</strong> to call <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> additi<strong>on</strong>alinstituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, and so <strong>on</strong> in a virtuouscycle of empowerment. Changing policies injust <strong>on</strong>e or two legal domains represents a start toempowering the poor, but the possibilities of legalempowerment will eventually require establishingmore open, inclusive and accountable instituti<strong>on</strong>ssystem-wide.This is a bold visi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Making</str<strong>on</strong>g> it a reality meansimplementing a host of specific publicpolicies around the world to tackle the everydayhumiliati<strong>on</strong>s of powerlessness and destituti<strong>on</strong>.Many legal covenants have been proposed andratified by the world community that are reas<strong>on</strong>ablestarting points <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> building inclusive domainsof power 1 — the challenge is to adapt the broadprinciples of instituti<strong>on</strong>al and legal re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m to reallife circumstances so they mean something to themultitude living <strong>on</strong> the edges of society. Implementati<strong>on</strong>seldom goes as planned, or as the Englishproverb has it: ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re’s many a slip ‘twixt cup andlip.’ This report discusses why those slips systematicallyoccur and how development practiti<strong>on</strong>erscan work with poor people to sustain momentumduring implementati<strong>on</strong> despite the tendency <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>pro-poor policy to be diluted and delayed while beingcarried out.Reports from the working groups <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chapters 1through 4 have analysed the way rights-expandingpolicies in the four domains of empowerment canblunt impoverishing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces. <strong>Legal</strong> recogniti<strong>on</strong> is afundamental step so that even the poorest citizenscan invoke the law to assert their rights anddemand protecti<strong>on</strong>s to which they are lawfully entitled.For that to occur, judicial instituti<strong>on</strong>s mustbe made resp<strong>on</strong>sive, transparent, and answerableto all, not just to the privileged few. Property rightsare central to the fight against poverty: they are ameans <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people to trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m limited assetsinto secure, productive resources, which theycan then use to enter the marketplace and claima fairer share of gains from exchange. Eventually,they could build their asset base to support a betterquality of life. Labour rights are another mechanismby which disadvantaged groups can obtaindecent and productive work. Such rights enablethe poor to claim their rightful share of the wealththey have helped to generate and to achieve theirhuman potential. Many poor people are caught inambiguous employment relati<strong>on</strong>ships where theirrights as workers are illdefined and their ability tomake occupati<strong>on</strong>s safe and n<strong>on</strong>-abusive is limited.Business rights round out the anti-poverty approachtaken by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>, in view of thefact that a significant share of the poor are eitherself-employed or already in charge of micro-enterprises.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se entrepreneurs are burdened byunnecessarily complicated procedures and regulati<strong>on</strong>s,and they lack legal instruments providingaccess to the credit markets that would allow themto expand their small business activities and totake more risks with new investments.It may be evident that the interdependent domainsof empowerment are vital to ending poverty, butwe must ask if, and to what extent, the underlyingrights are realisable. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong> has promptedour working group to address ways of puttingrights-expanding policies in place so they actuallyreach the poor. In Secti<strong>on</strong> 2, we discuss the numerousobstacles that policymakers must face andovercome in ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to implement rights-c<strong>on</strong>ferringprogrammemes. Understanding these obstacles isthe first step to overcoming them.284


2. Implementati<strong>on</strong>:Challenges andOpportunitiesImplementati<strong>on</strong> refers to the carrying out of publicpolicy. A public policy can be thought of as acourse of acti<strong>on</strong> (or purposeful inacti<strong>on</strong>) chosen bypublic authorities to c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>t a given problem orset of problems. Implementati<strong>on</strong> thus involves governmentor quasi-government organisati<strong>on</strong>s settingaside resources and organising specific activities toimprove society in line with announced plans. For<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor (<strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor) the relevant policies may includecitizen registrati<strong>on</strong> drives, land titling schemes,labour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> workers, whether in enterprises orhome-based, juridical recogniti<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal businesses,and many other c<strong>on</strong>crete activities.Table 5.1 lists representative specific re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msidentified by the different working groups that havebeen involved in preparing this volume. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are<strong>on</strong>ly illustrati<strong>on</strong>s, and may not necessarily be themost pressing required <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a particular country inachieving legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>al change. (For thecomplete record of recommended possible re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms,we refer the reader to the groups’ separate papersexploring the four domains of empowerment.) Itshould be self-evident that the policies suggestedin Table 5.1 are not all equally needed or feasible<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> every country. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers need to look at theTable 5.1 Sample <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msJustice• Effective, af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable and accessible systems of alternate dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>.• Improved identity registrati<strong>on</strong> systems, without user fees.• <strong>Legal</strong> simplifi cati<strong>on</strong> and standardisati<strong>on</strong> and legal literacy campaigns targeting the poor.• Str<strong>on</strong>ger legal aid systems and expanded legal service cadres with paralegals and law students.• Structural re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m enabling community-based groups to pool legal risks.Property• <strong>Legal</strong> recogniti<strong>on</strong> of joint registrati<strong>on</strong> of land rights and re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of discriminatory inheritance and divorce laws andpractices.• <strong>Legal</strong> guidelines <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced relocati<strong>on</strong>, including fair compensati<strong>on</strong>.• Recogniti<strong>on</strong> of a variety of land tenure, including customary rights, indigenous people’s rights, group rights, certificates,etc.• State land audits with fi ndings published to discourage illegal taking possessi<strong>on</strong> of public land.• Simplifi ed procedures to register and transfer land and propertyLabour• Fundamental rights at work, especially freedom of associati<strong>on</strong>, collective bargaining and n<strong>on</strong>-discriminati<strong>on</strong>.• Improved quality of labour regulati<strong>on</strong> and its en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement.• Inclusive approaches to social protecti<strong>on</strong>, delinked from the employment relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Labour rights (health and safety,hours of work, minimum income) extended to workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy.• More opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>, training and retraining.285


menu of possible <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to find the policies that are applicableto given situati<strong>on</strong>s and to particular problems ofpoverty and disempowerment.Implementati<strong>on</strong> sometimes c<strong>on</strong>jures up err<strong>on</strong>eousimpressi<strong>on</strong>s of a chain of command <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> publicpolicy, but this regimented image hides thedisorderly element of the true process. It is best toavoid getting locked into a visi<strong>on</strong> of public policyas a hierarchy of separate stages (<strong>on</strong>e of which isimplementati<strong>on</strong>), and to think instead of interactingspheres of policy activity all of which c<strong>on</strong>tributeto implementati<strong>on</strong>. We will navigate this looselyordered process more carefully with the policyroadmap in Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 of this chapter.Because it is an overarching set of aspirati<strong>on</strong>s,covering four mutually supporting domains ofempowerment, <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor itselfis not something that is usually ‘implemented’in the narrow sense of the term being used here.Implementati<strong>on</strong> entails identifiable projects andprogrammemes in different sectors, and many ofthese specific courses of government acti<strong>on</strong> mightbe empowering in different ways without everbearing the official label <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor. Seldom is c<strong>on</strong>structive pro-poor policypossible if the poor are the passive targets of statecentredre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m; a balanced legal empowermentstrategy is community-driven and grounded inlocal needs, which, however, can be translated int<strong>on</strong>ati<strong>on</strong>al-level re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> wider impact <strong>on</strong> upwardmobility (Golub 2003).In some cases, the positive outcomes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepoor depend up<strong>on</strong> government establishing newprocedures or instituti<strong>on</strong>s. (An example from theAndes countries is given in Box 5.1.) In othercases, the task is to revive an existing policy thatwas never fully or fairly en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced — <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance,a bill of rights that calls <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> treating every<strong>on</strong>e insociety equally. A third possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> aiding theBox 5.1 Removing Barriers toPublic <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>s C<strong>on</strong>tracts<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> development of public investment policies thatpromote the use of labour-based technologies hasimproved access of small local c<strong>on</strong>tractors to publicprocurement processes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> services and works inAndean countries. Activities range from c<strong>on</strong>tractingof micro-enterprises <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> routine road maintenance inrural areas, to involving them in waste collecti<strong>on</strong> andstreet cleaning in urban areas. An ILO study shows,however, that access of small local c<strong>on</strong>tractors topublic procurement is still very limited due to the existenceof a series of legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>al barriers.For example, countries may restrict c<strong>on</strong>tracts to enterprisesrecorded in the nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>tractor register orto recognised civil engineers or architects.A transparent in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> system about tenders needsto be implemented to facilitate the participati<strong>on</strong> ofsmall c<strong>on</strong>tractors in public works. Two alternativeshave proven workable: A ‘small c<strong>on</strong>tractor card’ and aregister <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> local c<strong>on</strong>tractors, enabling small c<strong>on</strong>tractorsto carry out small and medium-sized works inthe local area after passing certain prerequisites andminimum qualificati<strong>on</strong> criteria. Other possibilitiesinclude: subc<strong>on</strong>tracting c<strong>on</strong>sortiums and associativec<strong>on</strong>tracts <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>tractor collaborati<strong>on</strong>; specialc<strong>on</strong>tracting arrangements in projects receiving d<strong>on</strong>orfunding; preferential treatment of micro and smallenterprises in public procurement in Peru; and directc<strong>on</strong>tracting (i.e., <strong>on</strong>e bidder) <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> small c<strong>on</strong>tracts.See: José Yeng and Serge Cartier van Dissel,Improving access of small local c<strong>on</strong>tractors to publicprocurement — <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> experience of Andean Countries,ASIST Bulletin #18, ILO (September 2004).poor is to change or eliminate existing policies thathave outlived their usefulness or that have cometo serve new purposes now at variance with theiroriginal intent. Examples of the latter are col<strong>on</strong>ialera statutes regarding vagrancy, trespassing and<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour, many of which survive <strong>on</strong> the booksof many countries. Whatever their original functi<strong>on</strong>,these relics of col<strong>on</strong>ialism have the effectof criminalizing poor people. Archaic laws of this286


nature need to be rewritten or abolished to encouragebroad-based legal empowerment.Policy Initiati<strong>on</strong>Where a public policy originates is there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e aleading factor to c<strong>on</strong>sider with implementati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is also the questi<strong>on</strong> as to who proposes sucha policy and who <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulates the approach. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>degree of domestic enthusiasm and support is whatmatters most <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementati<strong>on</strong>, though externald<strong>on</strong>ors and internati<strong>on</strong>al agencies are a usefulsource of ideas <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. Often, a crisissuch as a natural disaster, or warfare, may act as apowerful stimulus <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> introducing new policies; butit is neither a necessary nor a sufficient c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementati<strong>on</strong>. In the wake of the Asian financialmeltdown in the sec<strong>on</strong>d half of the 1990s, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>instance, Ind<strong>on</strong>esia enacted a series of importantlabour law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that began with guaranteeingthe fundamental right of freedom of associati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first legislative change repealed provisi<strong>on</strong>s thatlimited representati<strong>on</strong> to a single government-c<strong>on</strong>trollednati<strong>on</strong>al federati<strong>on</strong> of trade uni<strong>on</strong>s, and putinto place a framework offering workers the chanceto <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m federati<strong>on</strong>s as they wished. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msmight well have been shelved under normal c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.Building <strong>on</strong> earlier work analysing political will<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> anti-corrupti<strong>on</strong> activities and <strong>on</strong> policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m(Brinkerhoff 2000; Brinkerhoff and Crosby 2002),the following initiating scenarios <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentcan be identified:1. Grassroots groups, social movements, membership-basedgroups of workers or of small businessowners mobilise and demand change. Some decisi<strong>on</strong>makers in the government resp<strong>on</strong>d favourably.This opti<strong>on</strong> provides motivati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> insiders whocan potentially champi<strong>on</strong> change.2.Choice of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mis based <strong>on</strong> country actors’ c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> andanalysis of opti<strong>on</strong>s, anticipated outcomes <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>various groups, and cost/benefits. When countryactors choose policies and acti<strong>on</strong>s based <strong>on</strong>their own assessments of the likely benefits tobe obtained, the alternatives and opti<strong>on</strong>s, andthe costs to be incurred, then <strong>on</strong>e can crediblyspeak of independently derived preferences andwillingness to act.3.Government initiates <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. Commitment is questi<strong>on</strong>ablewhen the initiative <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m comes largely fromexternal actors. Some degree of initiative fromcountry decisi<strong>on</strong>-makers must exist in order totalk meaningfully of political will.4.Government mobilises key stakeholders in supportof <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. Thisset up c<strong>on</strong>cerns the extent to which governmentactors c<strong>on</strong>sult with, engage, and mobilise <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor stakeholders. Do decisi<strong>on</strong>-makesreach out to members of civil societyand pro-poor groups to advocate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the changesenvisi<strong>on</strong>ed? Are legislators involved? Are there<strong>on</strong>going ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to build c<strong>on</strong>stituencies in favourof new <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms?5.Government publicly commits and allocatesresources to <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. To the extent that country decisi<strong>on</strong>-makersreveal their <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorpolicy preferences publicly and assign resourcesto achieve announced policy and programmemegoals, such acti<strong>on</strong>s indicate commitment tochange. When countries commit to changesfunded by outside d<strong>on</strong>or resources, the presenceof political will becomes unclear.6.Government supports c<strong>on</strong>tinuity of ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t. Anothersituati<strong>on</strong> is the assignment of resourcesand ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t over the l<strong>on</strong>g-term to achieve <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor goals. One-shot or episodicef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts would signal weak or wavering own-287


ership. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms,by their very nature, are l<strong>on</strong>g-term undertakings.7. Key actors m<strong>on</strong>itor <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor progress <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> learning and adaptati<strong>on</strong>. Itshows a level of commitment when country actorsestablish a system <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> tracking <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m progress, and activelymanage implementati<strong>on</strong> by adapting to emergingcircumstances over time. However, learning canalso apply to country decisi<strong>on</strong>-makers who havebeen able to observe <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor policies, practices, and programmemes fromother countries and who can selectively adoptthem <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their own use.8.D<strong>on</strong>ors club together into a joint programmemingstrategy, or multi-d<strong>on</strong>or group (e.g., through theHarm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> Alignment and Coordinati<strong>on</strong> approach).This opti<strong>on</strong> provides another possibility<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> outsiders to assess the possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change.While external support can be a str<strong>on</strong>g catalyst<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change, external micro-management can alsoeasily render the process too burdensome <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers and policy champi<strong>on</strong>s within government.It is important that the d<strong>on</strong>or role in <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor be supportive and notself-defeating.Be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e adopting any of these opti<strong>on</strong>s, thoughtshould be given as to whether to engage in several<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor domains,or sectors, at <strong>on</strong>ce, or to proceed with <strong>on</strong>e andthen transiti<strong>on</strong> to others. Also, <strong>on</strong>e must be <strong>on</strong>guard to ensure that a policy chosen does notsimply increase state power and patr<strong>on</strong>age in waysinc<strong>on</strong>sistent with pro-poor objectives. Agrarianre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m has often g<strong>on</strong>e wr<strong>on</strong>g, with the supposedbeneficiaries becoming victims. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> best guaranteeagainst such perverse developments is to bring thepoor themselves into the policy initiati<strong>on</strong> process.Civil societies, NGOs, membership-based organisati<strong>on</strong>sof employers and of workers, coaliti<strong>on</strong>s andnetworks all have a major role to play in generatingand articulating bottom-up demand. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> participatoryobjective often goes hand- in-hand withdecentralisati<strong>on</strong>.But the advantage of community engagement anddecentralised structures is not a universal law. Insome cases, central authorities may be the bestallies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor, because they can potentiallysidestep local spheres of interest in support ofmarginalized and disadvantaged communities. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ycould serve as counterweight <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor and minoritiesagainst what may be entrenched c<strong>on</strong>trol oflocal government by anti-poor facti<strong>on</strong>s. A c<strong>on</strong>creteexample is the key role played by the federal governmentof Brazil in combating <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour in remoterural areas of the country (ILO 2001: 25).Policy Champi<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> degree of initial government support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> anypolicy derives from domestic leaders who share apercepti<strong>on</strong> of a problem and who have agreed <strong>on</strong>how to solve it. One or a few of these people mayemerge as policy champi<strong>on</strong>s, or entrepreneurs,who make a policy their signature issue and driveit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward over time. Securing political will <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> anynew course of acti<strong>on</strong> needs champi<strong>on</strong>s to bringother government actors <strong>on</strong> board and precludepolicy spoilers from blocking introducti<strong>on</strong> of thepolicy. Having str<strong>on</strong>g advocates at high levels ofgovernment is vital to getting the legislative andexecutive arms to cooperate and follow through <strong>on</strong>policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.Policy champi<strong>on</strong>s within government may beemboldened by backing and pressure from civilsociety within the country. To start a c<strong>on</strong>troversialpolicy such as <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor,which threatens many vested interests (see below),domestic policy advocacy is especially important.That is another reas<strong>on</strong> why organising by the poorand their representati<strong>on</strong> of their rights are basic to288


Figure 5.2 Influences <strong>on</strong> Policy Implementati<strong>on</strong>: Empowering the PoorPolicy champi<strong>on</strong>sPolicy envir<strong>on</strong>ment(social structure,ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>text,political/administrativesystem, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality)Policy initiative(intended expansi<strong>on</strong>of justice, assetholding, labourand entrepreneurialrights)Policy stakeholders(beneficiaries, allies,practiti<strong>on</strong>ers, challengers)Policy characteristics(complexity, ambiguity,discord)Policy outcomeInstituti<strong>on</strong>al/legalprotecti<strong>on</strong>/ opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> excluded groupsthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’s empowerment agenda.A policy champi<strong>on</strong> can come <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward at any levelof government. Many <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor policies do not start out not at the nati<strong>on</strong>alcentre, but emerge from the periphery via local orregi<strong>on</strong>al governments. A mayor or town council, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, may want to take care of problems at anirregular housing settlement, an open air market ora waste disposal site. Acting pro-actively, the localgovernment may try to include the people wholive or work in these areas in finding the soluti<strong>on</strong>s.Perhaps more comm<strong>on</strong>ly, the local government maysimply go ahead with re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms devoid of popularparticipati<strong>on</strong>, sometimes triggering an empoweringreacti<strong>on</strong> as poor men and women move to legallyto protect themselves from the harm caused by thepolicy. In either scenario, the nati<strong>on</strong>al governmentmay be <strong>on</strong> the sidelines of implementati<strong>on</strong>.Protag<strong>on</strong>ists dedicated to the task of implementati<strong>on</strong>may emerge out of other stakeholder groups(see below), as well, not just from the public sector.Any individual with leadership skills, initiative,and commitment can play the role of policy champi<strong>on</strong>,though they may be most effective if theyalso have technical knowledge about the subject athand. Having several policy champi<strong>on</strong>s is generallybetter <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementati<strong>on</strong>.Forces Affecting Implementati<strong>on</strong>Once a policymaking process has been started, severalcomm<strong>on</strong> factors have been found to facilitateor impede reaching the desired policy c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>,notwithstanding the c<strong>on</strong>tent. Some of the generalinfluences <strong>on</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cern the peopleaffected by the policy, or the policy stakeholders.Another set of influential factors reflects attributesof the c<strong>on</strong>text in which the policy exists, or the policyenvir<strong>on</strong>ment. A third set is distinctive featuresor policy characteristics of the proposed course ofacti<strong>on</strong>. We can think of these three categories ofsignificant <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces as the ‘who’, the ‘where’, and the‘what’ of policy implementati<strong>on</strong>. (<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘how’ willbe dealt with in Secti<strong>on</strong>s 3 and 4, <strong>on</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong>roadmaps and pro-poor toolkits.) Figure 5.2presents a schematic summary of these influences<strong>on</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong> in the specific c<strong>on</strong>text ofempowering the poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> arrows in Figure 5.2 areshown as diminishing in size during the implementati<strong>on</strong>venture, to c<strong>on</strong>vey the idea that these tend289


to be fricti<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces that reduce the probabilityof fully attaining projected policy outcomes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>large initiating arrows also assume there is str<strong>on</strong>gpolitical will <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the policy, which may or may notbe true. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fricti<strong>on</strong>al influences <strong>on</strong> implementing<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor will test the resourcefulnessof policymakers seeking to carry outthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’s agenda. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor requires c<strong>on</strong>tinued vigilance to push backagainst inertia and the status quo.Policy StakeholdersA logical place to start when trying to understandinfluences <strong>on</strong> pro-poor policy implementati<strong>on</strong> is toenumerate the stakeholder groups and apprehendtheir stand <strong>on</strong> the issue being c<strong>on</strong>sidered. Stakeholdersare people with an interest in a policy, andwho have the capacity to move the policy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>wardor stop it in its tracks. Some of these groups maybe set up as <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entities, while others may beunorganised collectives with shared interests butno official representati<strong>on</strong> or recogniti<strong>on</strong>. Stakeholdersact out of regard <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their own advantage, asthey define it. 2 To implement policy requires a criticalmass of supportive c<strong>on</strong>stituencies and minimisati<strong>on</strong>or neutralisati<strong>on</strong> of the unsupportive groups.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> important thing to bear in mind in lookingat stakeholders is that they act in resp<strong>on</strong>seto ec<strong>on</strong>omic and political incentives. At its core,legal empowerment is about changing incentivesto induce poor people to be more creative andproductive by allowing them greater aut<strong>on</strong>omy andfreedom. Change agents are nevertheless cauti<strong>on</strong>edto be <strong>on</strong> guard against perverse incentivesthat could lead some c<strong>on</strong>stituencies to act in waysdetrimental to poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>.Accordingly, it is advisable to c<strong>on</strong>duct a stakeholderanalysis and to plot stakeholder interests andintenti<strong>on</strong>s regarding the problem that a particularpolicy seeks to address. 3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are many possible<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mats to use with stakeholder analysis, butthe usual practice is to start by enumerating thepossible c<strong>on</strong>stituencies. Examples from the landsector might include the following:• Individuals: landowners, landlords, tenants,shareholders, squatters, refugees, as well asbeneficiaries of specific programmemes.• Public sector: politicians, line ministries, provincial/municipal/districtdepartments.• Private sector: land developers, estate agents,notaries, lawyers, surveyors, planners, bankers,media.• Civil society: business associati<strong>on</strong>s, NGOs,CBOs, CSOs, faith-based groups, public policyresearch institutes, universities.• Traditi<strong>on</strong>al authorities: chiefs, elders.• Internati<strong>on</strong>al development partners: multilateralinstituti<strong>on</strong>s, bilateral agencies, private foundati<strong>on</strong>s,internati<strong>on</strong>al NGOs.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> next step, typically, is to estimate eachc<strong>on</strong>stituency’s positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> an issue, the intensityof its interest in the outcome (or policy salience),and the group’s relative power to affect the outcome.This may be tricky because any given set ofstakeholders need not have m<strong>on</strong>olithic interests.Policy cleavages are important because they affectthe possibility of building alliances across groups.Also any <strong>on</strong>e member of these groups may bel<strong>on</strong>gto several stakeholder categories, and this may alsopresent opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> communicati<strong>on</strong>, bargainingand coaliti<strong>on</strong>-building am<strong>on</strong>g the groups. Ingeneral, it is must be remembered that the c<strong>on</strong>figurati<strong>on</strong>of stakeholder interests and policy positi<strong>on</strong>sis not static.Sometimes the importance of the issue to thegroup and its potential influence <strong>on</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong>might be rated <strong>on</strong> a rough zero-to-ten scale(from no importance to vital). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> priority to beaccorded the group could also be quantified. Table290


Table 5.2 Illustrative Stakeholder MatrixStakeholderInterest in thePolicy(Pro/Neutral/C<strong>on</strong>)Salience of thePolicy(0-10)Influence <strong>on</strong> thePolicy(0-10)Priority <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Policymakers(Hi/Medium/Low)Group 1Group 2Group 3, etc.5.2 shows a generic stakeholder matrix, similarto the kind of tool policymakers might develop toidentify potential alliances and implementati<strong>on</strong>strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorpolicy initiative.Arch<strong>on</strong> Fung and Erik Wright (2003) suggest twogeneric strategies to c<strong>on</strong>tend with stakeholders:top-down adversarial strategies and participatorycollaborati<strong>on</strong>. Building alliances across stakeholdergroups is vital, which will turn <strong>on</strong> the networks andcoaliti<strong>on</strong>s to which they bel<strong>on</strong>g. Support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor will arise from stakeholderswho view it as good politics and a meansto build political support and legitimacy. D<strong>on</strong>orscan assist, but the driving <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change mustcome from within the country. Nati<strong>on</strong>al leadershipin debating the difficult issues is crucial.With regard to participatory collaborati<strong>on</strong>, agreementmay be absent about who should be involvedin decisi<strong>on</strong>s. Some stakeholders will not have aprearranged structure. Also, there may be no approvedinter-stakeholder process <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> developingcomm<strong>on</strong> policy positi<strong>on</strong>s. Such an instituti<strong>on</strong>alarrangement will there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e need to be expresslybrought together <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> purposes of implementing<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> challengesof establishing comm<strong>on</strong>ly agreed up<strong>on</strong> definiti<strong>on</strong>sof problem situati<strong>on</strong>s and identifying the relevantstakeholders must be overcome as a first step.Adversarial situati<strong>on</strong>s are even riskier <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor.Most of the time, disfavoured, disenfranchisedstakeholders stand to lose in c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong>s withbetter endowed groups. Resoluti<strong>on</strong> of the c<strong>on</strong>flictinginterests ranges al<strong>on</strong>g a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum from negotiati<strong>on</strong>to mediati<strong>on</strong>, to third-party adjudicati<strong>on</strong> or arbitrati<strong>on</strong>,to refusal to compromise at all. Adversarialstakeholders ordinarily enter into negotiati<strong>on</strong> whenthey see that is the best alternative compared towhat they could obtain ‘away from the bargainingtable’ (Ramirez 1999). Where c<strong>on</strong>flict already exists,a strategic starting point <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> development professi<strong>on</strong>alsis to understand stakeholder preferences<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> how to deal with the clash of interests.In thinking about stakeholder preferences, thereare four stylised stakeholders (shown in the middlebox of Figure 5.2, above) to c<strong>on</strong>sider: the policy’sbeneficiaries, obviously, but also its allies (whosupport the policy even though they may notbenefit directly), practiti<strong>on</strong>ers resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepolicy, and challengers of the policy. Some of thepossibilities are sketched out below; these areillustrative categories and, needless to say, thedescripti<strong>on</strong>s may not accurately depict any actualgroup in any given country. As noted, real groupsmay straddle the generic categories or switch backand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>th am<strong>on</strong>g them, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example from being<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor challengers at <strong>on</strong>epoint in time to being <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor allies at another period.BeneficiariesPoor people are the target beneficiaries of <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor policies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are the ma-291


jority of the populati<strong>on</strong> in many countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> term‘the poor’ is a c<strong>on</strong>venience, of course, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this multitudeis far from a m<strong>on</strong>olithic c<strong>on</strong>stituency despitesharing hunger, ill health, inadequate housing andother pathologies of poverty. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y live in remote ruralvillages and in urban shantytowns. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y work assubsistence farmers, agricultural labourers, domesticworkers, street vendors, and trash recyclers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>yare members of underrepresented ethnic minorities— often internal or external migrants seeking improvedopportunities in a new area where they lackclear legal status. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y have been displaced by warand civil unrest, and they are indigenous people whohave been left out and left behind by the dominantsociety. A lopsided number of the poor are women,who usually have home and family resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities<strong>on</strong> top of any work they have found outside thehome. It is useful to have a segmented census ofthe poor as a starting point <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor work in any country, to know who theyare, where they are located, and to what extent theirinterests are aligned.Beneficiaries of legal empowerment need to haveas big a hand as possible in initiating and designingthe relevant policies. Even though they lackphysical or financial resources, and organisati<strong>on</strong>alresources and social capital in many locales, thepoor always have a passive capacity to derail legalre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms aimed at them. If the poor are afraid of oraverse to playing their designated role in implementati<strong>on</strong>,the best intended policy would cometo nothing. It is critical that their views be airedand taken into account by policymakers to makesure the proposed course of acti<strong>on</strong> fits what poorstakeholders are prepared to do.Because poor stakeholders are diverse, legal empowermentplat<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms may have surprisingly unevenimpact if officials are inattentive. An illustrati<strong>on</strong>comes from South Africa. Residents of extra-legalsettlements in South Africa can be given individualdeeds to their homes. Yet, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> some inhabitants theresult is a decrease in security of tenure. Ownershipis registered in the name of <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e memberof each household, to the disadvantage of womenand members of the extended family. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> newproperty owners also become liable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> paying localtaxes and service charges, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing some to sell becausethey cannot af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d to pay. A few people who,by statute, come to own dwellings, cannot not livein them because in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal street committees decideother people should take possessi<strong>on</strong> of the properties(Cousins et al. 2005). Thus an apparently equitablepolicy to expand asset-holding rights endsup having an unequal impact <strong>on</strong> poverty, becauseeven within these very poor residential areas, materialgoods and power are not distributed equally.Policymakers might have minimised this outcomeby differentiating am<strong>on</strong>g beneficiaries and payinggreater attenti<strong>on</strong> to existing social practices thathave widespread legitimacy (see the later discussi<strong>on</strong>of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s).Poor women present a particular challenge <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor because insome cases their advantage can be to the disadvantageof the male half of the poor populati<strong>on</strong>. In EastAfrica, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance, women tend to enjoy ‘use rights’to land (see further discussi<strong>on</strong> of the spectrum ofland rights, below) as wives and mothers, but lacktransfer rights due to customs that reserve these <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>men. Women there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e are without secure claim to anatural resource they use <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> daily supplies of fuel,water and food. <strong>Legal</strong> insecurity inhibits ec<strong>on</strong>omicprogress because women cannot make decisi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> expanding or developing land (UNEP 2004:99).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir fathers, husbands and s<strong>on</strong>s are likely to balkat ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to implement expanded women’s rightsin this important ec<strong>on</strong>omic realm, because theywould compromise men’s rights to the same assets.Women’s community based organisati<strong>on</strong>s may be theanswer. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se have proven somewhat effective inpreserving women’s land access in Mexico, though292


effective land c<strong>on</strong>trol does not necessarily follow(Radel 2005).Poor indigenous people, who represent 15 percentof the world’s poor but <strong>on</strong>ly 5 percent ofits populati<strong>on</strong> (ILO 2007: 27), are another specialtest <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor due tophysical or social isolati<strong>on</strong> from the influence ofthe governance claimed by a nati<strong>on</strong>-state. Someindigenous people are nomadic; some have beendispossessed de jure or de facto of their ancestrallands. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y may speak a separate language. Indigenouspeople often live in remote sites with highec<strong>on</strong>omic potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> water, timber, or medicinalplants, but lack legal instruments to preventover-extracti<strong>on</strong> of natural resources by outsiders.All these characteristics make it all the moreimportant <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> government to reach these wouldbebeneficiaries. (See Box 5.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an example ofa participatory approach that helped indigenouspeople in Philippines assert claims to their ancestralrealm.)Box 5.2 Ancestral Domain, Sustainable Development, and Protecti<strong>on</strong>Plan of the Bago and Bugkalot Tribes.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Philippines Indigenous Peoples Rights Act (IPRA) of1997 c<strong>on</strong>solidated bills related to ancestral domains andlands, and internati<strong>on</strong>al agreements <strong>on</strong> the recogniti<strong>on</strong> ofland/domain rights of the indigenous peoples. Metagora(a project funded by OECD) in the Philippines developedevidence-based assessment methods and tools combiningquantitative and qualitative approaches. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>study measures four aspects of the rights of indigenouspeoples to their ancestral domains and lands: the indigenouspeoples’ percepti<strong>on</strong>s and awareness of their rights,the enjoyment or violati<strong>on</strong>s of these rights, the governmentmeasures and customary laws <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the realisati<strong>on</strong>of these rights, and the availability of mechanisms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>redressing violati<strong>on</strong>s or fulfilling rights.Metagora’s method of work is based <strong>on</strong> a bottom-up approachc<strong>on</strong>sisting of:• <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing with the shareholders in pilot countries, toidentitfy issues in human rights, democracy; andgovernance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> which evidence-based assessment ishighly relevant;• Applying statistical methods and tools to that particularc<strong>on</strong>text;• Assessing these methods <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their capacity to providepolicy relevant results;• Providing stakeholders with a shared knowledge <strong>on</strong> thepolicy issues at stake; drawing universal less<strong>on</strong>s fromthe local experiences;• Formulating recommendati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> further applicati<strong>on</strong>of the tested methods elsewhere.Three tribes covering public ancestral domains in threeregi<strong>on</strong>s of the Philippines were covered by the survey.Major resp<strong>on</strong>dents were representative samples of thetribal populati<strong>on</strong> stratified according to selected criteriathat are in c<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong>ance with the customs and traditi<strong>on</strong>sof the target populati<strong>on</strong>. N<strong>on</strong>-indigenous people resp<strong>on</strong>dents,especially the governance stakeholders, alsocomprised the sec<strong>on</strong>dary resp<strong>on</strong>dents of the survey.This is a case of objective survey data having policy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce<strong>on</strong> account of the involvement of an internati<strong>on</strong>al projectin partnership with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Human Rights ofthe Philippines, its Regi<strong>on</strong>al Offices, the Nati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>on</strong> Indigenous People, and Nati<strong>on</strong>al StatisticalCoordinati<strong>on</strong> Board (NSCB).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> data and evidence gathered had the positive c<strong>on</strong>sequenceof making the nati<strong>on</strong>al and regi<strong>on</strong>al governmentauthorities take the implementati<strong>on</strong> of the provisi<strong>on</strong>s ofthe Philippines Indigenous Peoples Rights Act seriously,so that the rights of indigenous peoples are settled, aproactive public policy approach is taken, and fundsprovided under the law are allocated properly to benefitthe indigenous people.Source: Metagora Training Materials. Ref:http://www.metagora.org.293


At the nati<strong>on</strong>al level, a society’s failure to provideopportunities to all in an ethnically diverse populati<strong>on</strong>(poor and not-poor alike) is found in somestudies to be a drag <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance,making it harder <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a country to grow its way outof poverty (ILO 2007: 9-10). Policymakers need toc<strong>on</strong>sider how ethnic and religious cleavages within acountry, al<strong>on</strong>g with traditi<strong>on</strong>al caste or gender-basedexclusi<strong>on</strong>s and oligarchic traditi<strong>on</strong>s of dominati<strong>on</strong>,affect the distributi<strong>on</strong> of wealth and income, andthe projected likelihood of empowering re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se power relati<strong>on</strong>s may have a significant impact<strong>on</strong> the chances of implementing <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor. We return to the questi<strong>on</strong>s of theec<strong>on</strong>omic and social c<strong>on</strong>text later in Secti<strong>on</strong> 2.Allies<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main allied stakeholders of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor policies are pro-poor communityassociati<strong>on</strong>s and activists of civil society. Someof these stakeholders will be local social acti<strong>on</strong>or advocacy groups, such as the Ind<strong>on</strong>esian <strong>Legal</strong>Aid Foundati<strong>on</strong> whose missi<strong>on</strong> is to defend poorpeople in court and expand their rights. Allies mayalso include professi<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>s sympatheticto the plight of the excluded and have-nots. Forexample, Ecuador’s Associati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> SchoolDeans supports legal assistance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the indigent inthat country. Nati<strong>on</strong>al bar associati<strong>on</strong>s are engagedin similar activities in many nati<strong>on</strong>s.Certain politicians may come out as allies. It is notuncomm<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, to find even somewhatdisreputable politicians offering to use public landto woo voters’ support in slum areas. Such pers<strong>on</strong>smay not be reliable allies, however. More dependablewill be the genuine policy champi<strong>on</strong>s, who haveemerged from am<strong>on</strong>g the nati<strong>on</strong>al or local politicalleadership to make a progressive name <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> themselvesas friends of legal empowerment.Some commercial enterprises, and particularlylarger companies and multinati<strong>on</strong>al corporati<strong>on</strong>s,may fall into the camp of policy allies <strong>on</strong> certainoccasi<strong>on</strong>s. Over 3,000 corporati<strong>on</strong>s in morethan 100 countries have joined the UN’s GlobalCompact, which commits them to support highstandards in the areas of the envir<strong>on</strong>ment, humanrights and labour rights (UN 2007). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se firmsoften say they would like to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ge partnerships withpoor communities in the developing world to createbusiness models that are sustainable, equitableand embedded in the local culture (Hart 2005).Some signatories are turning to the poor as businesspartners, suppliers, or distributors.Nairobi, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, has a productive alliancebetween in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal entrepreneurs and larger businesses.Two business associati<strong>on</strong>s joined with thestreet vendors’ organisati<strong>on</strong> in a dialogue with localauthorities to improve the status of street vending.Street vendors in Kenya’s capital city are subject toharassment and demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> bribes from city inspectors.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> uncertainty <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces the vendors to limit theirstock and hinders their productivity and income. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>two c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>s had wanted to driveout street vending because of litter and crowding,but came around because, am<strong>on</strong>g other things, ofa growing realisati<strong>on</strong> that the outdoor presence ofvendors limits crime and thus is good <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> every<strong>on</strong>e’sbusiness. Interestingly, the vendors’ group wants itsmembers to pay licensing fees, <strong>on</strong> the argument thatpaying gives the members legal cover and providesleverage <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> government services (Kamunyori 2007).It should go without saying that these observati<strong>on</strong>sdo not mean every self-described ally of the pooris a true friend of the legal empowerment agenda.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> real world is far more subtle and complex thanthat. Some grassroots groups may feel threatenedby <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor if they do nothave the lead in directing the movement. Stakeholderanalysis cannot be d<strong>on</strong>e by mechanisticallyapplying generic labels to pre-determined groups of294


actors and assuming they will behave according totheir category.Practiti<strong>on</strong>ersA third important set of generic stakeholders arepractiti<strong>on</strong>ers — mainly the government officials,court officers, and others who draft, interpretand administer the land laws, labour statutesand commercial regulati<strong>on</strong>s in a country. Despitesometimes having low positi<strong>on</strong>s in the bureaucratichierarchy of government, these officials can and dowield c<strong>on</strong>siderable effective discreti<strong>on</strong>ary authorityover implementati<strong>on</strong>.One comm<strong>on</strong> problem is that permits, businesslicenses, tax assessments and the likeare sources of power and potential illegal incomethrough bribes, kickbacks and other ‘rent-seeking’behaviour. 4 Even the abstruse text describing manyof these regulati<strong>on</strong>s provides low-level governmentemployees with power, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> citizens cannot decode legaljarg<strong>on</strong> easily <strong>on</strong> their own. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> interests and attitudesof government officials at all levels must there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ebe factored into the implementati<strong>on</strong> process. InBeijing, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, law en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement officers andlocal authorities look the other way when rural-urbanmigrant entrepreneurs do not comply fully withlicense requirements and instead lease licenses illegallyfrom local residents. This illicit license-leasingpractice is sustained because bureaucrats profit fromit (He 2005). Streamlining the business registrati<strong>on</strong>process in line with <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorgoals would threaten illegal but routine bureaucraticincome in China’s capital city.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se comments do not imply that bureaucrats arealways spoilers of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m. A new programmeme mayalso mean that staff members gain promoti<strong>on</strong>s,have interesting new resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities, or have trainingopportunities or other perquisites. Within everygovernment executive agency or judicial instituti<strong>on</strong>there may be potential policy champi<strong>on</strong>s, who cometo identify with a particular soluti<strong>on</strong> to a socialproblem and make strenuous ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t to get it implemented.As noted, entrepreneurial ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t by policychampi<strong>on</strong>s in elected and administrative office is ac<strong>on</strong>sistent theme in successful policy implementati<strong>on</strong>around the world.ChallengersA final c<strong>on</strong>stituency to c<strong>on</strong>sider is rival stakeholdersthat challenge disenfranchised people exercisingnew rights or reviving latent <strong>on</strong>es. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se competingor oppositi<strong>on</strong>al stakeholders may include <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eignbusinesses and large domestic companies, but alsocover many small landlords, mine owners, shopkeepers,and m<strong>on</strong>eylenders, plus some lawyers,engineers, and similar specialised experts who tendto prefer the status quo. We should be careful aboutbrushing any class of people with too broad a stroke,but numerous local elites and professi<strong>on</strong>als arelikely to feel threatened by c<strong>on</strong>fident and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cefulpoor people and may try to pre-empt improvementsin poor people’s status and income. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>yers, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>example, may lose the upper hand with clients iflaws are translated into everyday language or if inexpensivec<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ums are made widelyavailable.A comm<strong>on</strong> and tricky problem of implementati<strong>on</strong> iswhen c<strong>on</strong>tending stakeholders do not try to block re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msoutright, but subtly manipulate emerging policies(and especially d<strong>on</strong>or-driven programmemes)to their advantage — a phenomen<strong>on</strong> known as ‘elitecapture’ (Decker 2005). This distorti<strong>on</strong> is chr<strong>on</strong>icwith <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor activities.In many Asian countries, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example prospectivetitling programmemes often have the perverse effectof inducing speculators to buy up land ahead oftime from squatters at slightly better than in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malprices. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> squatters come out ahead in the shortterm, but pay the opportunity cost of not waitingl<strong>on</strong>g enough to get the main benefit of the titling295


programme — which accrues to the people withdeeper pockets. Low income and vulnerability leadto a safety-first calculati<strong>on</strong>, so squatters reas<strong>on</strong>ablyprefer to have their cash immediately. C<strong>on</strong>trary tothe stated intenti<strong>on</strong> of the titling programmeme,however, elites capture most of the gains from it.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sequential and c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al release of funds is<strong>on</strong>e strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> countering the persistent problem ofelite capture (Platteau 2004).Policy Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and C<strong>on</strong>textualAnalysisCrucial as stakeholders are to implementati<strong>on</strong>,even more basic is the country c<strong>on</strong>text. In mostcountries, a minority of the better-off holds disproporti<strong>on</strong>ateinfluence over the local and nati<strong>on</strong>alpolicy apparatus due to its more sophisticatedknowledge about markets, to its greater businessand political c<strong>on</strong>tacts, and to its better access tofinance. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se power structures influence the decisi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> who prevails in the bargaining, competiti<strong>on</strong>and cooperati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g stakeholders, and alsoc<strong>on</strong>strain many other facets of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor. It is impossible to decide what sorts ofre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to attempt and to determine what it will totake to carry them without first coming to an h<strong>on</strong>estassessment of the country policy envir<strong>on</strong>ment.A clear-eyed c<strong>on</strong>textual analysis should there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eguide all decisi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> if, when and how to go <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>wardwith <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor policiesand provide guidance during implementati<strong>on</strong>. AsFigure 5.2 suggests, the most important c<strong>on</strong>straintsset by the nati<strong>on</strong>al socio-political c<strong>on</strong>text are:• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> domestic social structure, especially itsgender, class and ethnic makeup, plus culturalattitudes toward participati<strong>on</strong> and equality.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>text — including the distributi<strong>on</strong>of wealth and income, and the level and rateof ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> characteristics of the state — both the politicaland the administrative system.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> extent of ec<strong>on</strong>omic and political in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malityand tensi<strong>on</strong>s with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and officially recognisedsystems.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are the critical factors <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>textual analysisand the parameters within which practiti<strong>on</strong>ersmust operate as they try to steer implementati<strong>on</strong> oflegal empowerment re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.Social StructureSeveral important points regarding social structurewere already implied in the discussi<strong>on</strong> of stakeholders,which emphasised the task of buildingwinning coaliti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change am<strong>on</strong>g clashingc<strong>on</strong>stituencies. Thus, a country with fewer poorpeople relative to its populati<strong>on</strong> will likely find iteasier to integrate them into the legal and ec<strong>on</strong>omicsystem compared to a country with morepoor people (though the poor also may be easierto ignore when their numbers are lower). Similarly,a homogeneous country will also find empoweringpeople at the bottom takes less ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t compared toa country where the populati<strong>on</strong> is deeply divided bylanguage, religi<strong>on</strong> or nati<strong>on</strong>al origin. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> absolutegap between rich and poor also matters, with asmaller gap facilitating implementati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor policies. A society wherewomen have c<strong>on</strong>siderable legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> willhave less ground to make up with empowering poorwomen than another society. Whether the socialand ec<strong>on</strong>omic cleavages are cumulative or crosscutting(that is, to what extent does membershipin a particular religious community or ethnic groupcorrelate with discriminati<strong>on</strong>, low income, exclusi<strong>on</strong>from power, and other negative attributes).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are given social facts at any point in time,though they can change in a country due to ec<strong>on</strong>omicgrowth, human migrati<strong>on</strong>, mass educati<strong>on</strong>,and exposure to media, am<strong>on</strong>g other factors. Poli-296


cymakers must tailor their empowerment strategiesto the structure of particular societies.Cultural factors are crucial to the social structure,as well. Assorted traditi<strong>on</strong>s and customarypractices colour the systems of propertyrights, c<strong>on</strong>tract en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement and dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>that the poor typically use. Indigenous people areparticularly likely to have elaborate but officiallyn<strong>on</strong>-existent systems in place <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> organising ec<strong>on</strong>omiclife. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re may be a large gap here betweenthe shared norms and values of the beneficiaries oflegal empowerment versus their stakeholder allies(not to menti<strong>on</strong> their rivals or opp<strong>on</strong>ents). Thatcultural distance makes it harder to come up withworkable and effective empowerment instrumentsand activities (see additi<strong>on</strong>al discussi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malinstituti<strong>on</strong>s, below).Another important social structure c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> isthat many societies and subcultures reflect hierarchicaland patriarchal power structures that mayimpinge <strong>on</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong> of legal empowerment,which is predicated <strong>on</strong> broad participati<strong>on</strong> of thebeneficiaries in decisi<strong>on</strong>s and the levelling effectsof ec<strong>on</strong>omic rights. Great tact may be needed tofind socially acceptable yet effective means ofinvolving, say, women or members of historicallyexcluded minorities in choosing and implementingpolicies that expand the ambit of empowerment.Development practiti<strong>on</strong>ers need to pay close attenti<strong>on</strong>to these cultural factors when they c<strong>on</strong>siderhow to carry out <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.Ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>textA country’s social structure cannot be isolated inpractice from who holds the country’s wealth andexercises ec<strong>on</strong>omic power. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> distributi<strong>on</strong> patternmay reflect historical injustice whereby a privilegedfew used their political influence and access tothe justice system to legitimise unfair claims toproperty. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> more unequal the initial pattern ofownership of land, capital, and other productiveassets, the more cautious will re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers have to beabout regularising the system of ec<strong>on</strong>omic rights.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no advantage to the poor from locking inplace deep pre-existing inequities in proprietorship— though to correct those inequities compensati<strong>on</strong>must usually be paid to the pre-existing assetholders, which may be both financially costly andpolitically risky due to the resistance it is likely tospark. It is important to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’s agendathat <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms aredesigned in a manner that braces the claims ofthe poor to assets without amplifying the existingskewed allocati<strong>on</strong> of property.Land is probably the most difficult ec<strong>on</strong>omicresource to manage, both because its supply islimited and because so many poor people dependdirectly <strong>on</strong> land <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their survival. Indigenouspeoples, and pastoralist and subsistence farmersmust assure their use of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests, pastures andarable fields, but, as menti<strong>on</strong>ed earlier, that bringsthem into head-<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>flict with richer claimantsto the same limited resources. Land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms haveproven a c<strong>on</strong>undrum in many countries due to theexpense and complexity of managing overlappingclaims to the identical resource.In additi<strong>on</strong> to how a nati<strong>on</strong>’s ‘ec<strong>on</strong>omic pie’ isdivided up, the overall size of the ‘pie’ also influencesthe extent of absolute poverty and hence theurgency of poor people’s empowerment and thescale of the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t needed to c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>t that socialproblem. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth makes it easier to redistributeassets to the poor, yet, ir<strong>on</strong>ically, growth isalso an unsettling <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor.Acase in point is redevelopment of the vastsquatter settlement of Dharavi, in Mumbai,India. As the land has soared in value, the city andstate have advanced plans to replace the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maltownship with upscale development. Because297


Dharavi’s residents lack ownership rights their abilityto defend their homes and shops is limited. Fortunately,direct acti<strong>on</strong> and advocacy from civil societyhas gotten the government to agree to provide smallapartments to the residents who will be displaced.That is not the end of the story, however. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seredevelopment plans can be drawn up without anyc<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>, and it is unclear who within Dharavi’spopulati<strong>on</strong> will get the new living units and worksites. Mumbai has sky-high real estate prices andthe state and the private developers still stand toearn huge amounts over and above the cost of thismitigati<strong>on</strong> ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t (Patel 2007). On the other hand,mitigati<strong>on</strong> may not have been <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>thcoming at allwere it not <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dynamic ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s inMumbai.With the clear excepti<strong>on</strong> of many programmemesinvolving the transfer of land andproperty, the financial cost of empowerment programmemesmay be modest. Since some elementsof <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor are revenueneutral, it is possible to pick the resource neutralelements first, or else the <strong>on</strong>es that require limitedexpenditure of resources. Special attenti<strong>on</strong> shouldbe paid to low-cost ways to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce property rights,guarantee c<strong>on</strong>tracts, and provide fair resoluti<strong>on</strong>of business and commercial disputes. Still, eventhese activities will slow to a crawl if the countrydoes not find enough funds to pay <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> them.Empowering the poor is a l<strong>on</strong>g-time endeavor so<strong>on</strong>going budget support is problematic. Take manyof the emerging market ec<strong>on</strong>omies in Asia. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ystill frequently underpay their judges and allowtheir courts to languish with inadequate facilities.Many of these legal systems are swampedwith a backlog of cases and are widely accused ofcorrupti<strong>on</strong>. Hence, fast ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth does notnecessarily put an end to resource scarcities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>implementati<strong>on</strong> if change is not a high priority.Political SystemPolitical system variables (i.e., factors affectingthe demand side of government) are crucial <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>implementati<strong>on</strong> and need to be taken apart andlooked at carefully. To combat legal disempowerment,there is no substitute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> collective acti<strong>on</strong> bypoor men and women to push <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rights and protecti<strong>on</strong>s,as in the Mumbai case cited above. Whendoing c<strong>on</strong>textual analysis, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, practiti<strong>on</strong>ersmust c<strong>on</strong>sider whether farmers, residents, workers,c<strong>on</strong>sumers and other c<strong>on</strong>stituencies have legalprotecti<strong>on</strong> to organise and petiti<strong>on</strong> the governmentor bargain with private entities to redress theirgrievances. In countries where these basic rightsare neglected or suppressed, <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor will be harder to carry out. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> right toorganise does not exist in a vacuum separated fromactual organisati<strong>on</strong>s, and thus the level of developmentof civil society is another important influence<strong>on</strong> the diagnosis <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy implementati<strong>on</strong>.It is easier to carry out <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor in countries with str<strong>on</strong>g community organisati<strong>on</strong>s,occupati<strong>on</strong>al membership groups or pro-poorpolitical parties, than where such social capital isabsent.As we have stressed, implementati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor usually involves communityparticipati<strong>on</strong>, sometimes through <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal venues setup <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the purpose or else through the establishedmechanisms of local government. Simply makingparticipatory procedures available, however,is not sufficient because the better-off and morec<strong>on</strong>nected members of communities tend to takeadvantage of them. Barbara Pozz<strong>on</strong>i and NaliniKumar (2005) describe two related <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of socialexclusi<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal, which refers to the poor anddisadvantaged not showing up at meetings, andsubstantive, which refers to their not speaking upin these venues. In India, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, local selfgovernmentappears to be working reas<strong>on</strong>ably well,298


ut some community members report being toointimidated to c<strong>on</strong>tradict local leaders and governmentadministrators (Viswanathan and Srivastava2007: 72). Social mobilisati<strong>on</strong> of the poor canhelp make participatory procedures in governmentwork closer to the way they are meant to.<strong>Legal</strong> empowerment is sometimes also facilitatedby democratic competiti<strong>on</strong> and free discussi<strong>on</strong>of policy issues at the nati<strong>on</strong>al level, whichinduces leaders seeking majority support to viewith policy proposals favourable to disadvantagedcitizens. But these are not panaceas. Proceduraldemocratic rule is now quite comm<strong>on</strong> in the world,yet empirical studies show countries experiencingdemocratic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m do not have systematicallybetter poverty outcomes (Ross 2006). For example,democratic countries are just as capable asdictatorships at carrying out government austerityprogrammemes that fall most heavily <strong>on</strong> the poor(Lindenberg and Devarajan 1993).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> procedural democracies are not at all c<strong>on</strong>sistentin the extent to which they protect minorities,root out political corrupti<strong>on</strong> and preventstate-sp<strong>on</strong>sored violence against citizens. Oftenthe leadership positi<strong>on</strong>s in these countries aredominated by the same social stratum that was incharge be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e the advent of procedural democracyand competitive politics. In some societies thisdominant group’s role is legitimated by religi<strong>on</strong>or traditi<strong>on</strong>, and deferential attitudes <strong>on</strong> the partof the poor may add another stumbling block toempowerment. One explanati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>omicdisparities that persist under democracy is theholdover of identity politics that divide the poor(Varshnay 2005). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re may also be deep rootedpatr<strong>on</strong>-client networks that push down the poor(more <strong>on</strong> this topic later).Take the example of Philippines. Its governmentis chosen in c<strong>on</strong>tested electi<strong>on</strong>s. Thousands ofcommunity based organisati<strong>on</strong>s exist in Manila andelsewhere, so there is a str<strong>on</strong>g civil society. Philippineshas a nati<strong>on</strong>al housing finance programmemeto regularise the city’s vast in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlements,implementati<strong>on</strong> of which is left to partnershipsbetween community groups, local governments,and the private sector. Local governments are alsorequired to set aside land <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> relocati<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsettlers and to compile lists of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal settlers whoare eligible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> relocati<strong>on</strong>. Yet even in this relativelybenign political envir<strong>on</strong>ment, the community groupstend to have limited influence and evicti<strong>on</strong>s andc<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> of land to commercial uses c<strong>on</strong>tinuesapace (Shatkin 2000).H<strong>on</strong>duras and Nicaragua have analogous problemsin rural areas. Land and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>estry laws favour thepoor <strong>on</strong> paper, but practice is different. In Nicaragua,c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al and legislative provisi<strong>on</strong>sexist <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the demarcati<strong>on</strong> and titling of indigenousterritories. Yet the government c<strong>on</strong>tinues to grantindustrial logging c<strong>on</strong>cessi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> community landswithout fulfilling these requirements. In H<strong>on</strong>duras,small-scale <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>est producers have use rights butseldom can meet transacti<strong>on</strong> costs of securingpermits and other approvals, owing to regulatorycomplexity and bureaucratic corrupti<strong>on</strong>. This <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cesthem to rely <strong>on</strong> timber traders to secure permitsand other approvals, which, in turn, fuels collusi<strong>on</strong>between traders and public officials, and elite captureof community <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>est management rights (Wellset al. 2004). Again, the quality of democraticinstituti<strong>on</strong>s in this pair of countries appears to varyaccording to the class and income of the citizensusing them.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se anecdotes obviously do not mean dictatorshipsare c<strong>on</strong>sistently better at c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>ting povertythan are countries classified as democratic. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reare examples throughout history of authoritarianregimes that carried out successful land re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms andother pro-poor policies; yet there have undoubtedly299


een a far greater number of authoritarian regimesthat did little or nothing to improve the health andwell-being of ordinary citizens. We need to look bey<strong>on</strong>dpolitical labels when designing implementati<strong>on</strong>strategies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.It is important to think of political systems asshades of grey when it comes to empowering thepoor. At the far end of the pallet are systems ofarbitrary pers<strong>on</strong>al rule, which are typically quiteclosed regarding grassroots participati<strong>on</strong> in policymaking,but which may be open to pro-poor policiesif the regime is a populist <strong>on</strong>e that depends <strong>on</strong>mass support. Dictatorships blend into more openand competitive systems where the poor may haveprogressively greater scope to sway public policy,but where the rich may still exercise hegem<strong>on</strong>y <strong>on</strong>key political ec<strong>on</strong>omy issues. Happily, there arefewer political systems today where poor peoplecannot organise at all to have some countervailinginfluence <strong>on</strong> government decisi<strong>on</strong>s; but in anumber of countries, freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> isstill being denied (ILO 2004: 1-2). And even inthe most receptive political systems the influenceof the poor is difficult to trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m into extensivepower. Development practiti<strong>on</strong>ers should be carefulnot let prec<strong>on</strong>cepti<strong>on</strong>s about regimes blind them tothese possibilities.Administrative state<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> supply side of political systems also needs tobe c<strong>on</strong>sidered to understand implementati<strong>on</strong> probabilities.How capable is the public administrati<strong>on</strong>?Does the state have the capacity to provide physicalsafety, to secure pers<strong>on</strong>al bel<strong>on</strong>gings, to settledisputes fairly, and to provide other public goodsto society? Does it possess the pers<strong>on</strong>nel, skills,systems, and infrastructure to carry out these corefuncti<strong>on</strong>s? Even political will cannot drive re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>min the face of binding c<strong>on</strong>straints <strong>on</strong> the capacityof instituti<strong>on</strong>s charged with delivering the mandateof empowerment. High-capacity states are <strong>on</strong>esthat implement policies efficiently, predictably, andin the manner intended. High-capacity states mayor may not be democratic, but they can carry outthe <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor agenda if thatis what the leadership wants. In very low-capacitystates, <strong>on</strong> the other hand, supportive leadership isstill beneficial except the follow-through capabilityis missing. Residents must there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e improvise andfigure out how to protect assets and resolve disputesthrough pragmatic means, such as aligningwith a political patr<strong>on</strong> (see discussi<strong>on</strong> of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malgovernance below).Administrative weakness is usually rooted in lackof human and financial resources, but a viciouscycle rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces the problem. A World Bank reportargues: Burdensome or extraneous business andlabour market official regulati<strong>on</strong>s drive people intothe shadow ec<strong>on</strong>omy, while a collective percepti<strong>on</strong>of ineffectiveness of the state’s acti<strong>on</strong>s gives riseto a social norm of n<strong>on</strong>-compliance with taxes andregulati<strong>on</strong>s, which further undermines the state’scapacity to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce the law and to provide publicservices (Perry et al. 2007). However, the methodologyunderlying such studies has come under serioustechnical criticism (Berg and Cazes, 2007).Bureaucratic corrupti<strong>on</strong> can also be a major weakeningfactor, especially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor who lack thewherewithal to pay bribes to make things happenwithin the bureaucracy. For people with means, <strong>on</strong>the other hand, the civil service may seem capableenough because, unlike the poor, they can pay <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>individualised special treatment. Thus bureaucraticcorrupti<strong>on</strong> will tend to rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce the existingc<strong>on</strong>figurati<strong>on</strong> of wealth and power. In cases wherepublic sector wages are low and virtually everythingthe civil service does is <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> sale, it may be almostimpossible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor to get public administrati<strong>on</strong>to work in their favour. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers would have to address corrupti<strong>on</strong>300


e<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e taking <strong>on</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong>, or choose to workin sectors where government employees are moreprofessi<strong>on</strong>al and trustworthy. 5Attitudes of public servants are also significant.Receptivity of state instituti<strong>on</strong>s to the agenda oflegal empowerment is as much about changing thebureaucratic mindset as it is about new processesor additi<strong>on</strong>al resources. Too often public functi<strong>on</strong>aries<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a variety of reas<strong>on</strong>s lack a service orientati<strong>on</strong>and see their job as an entitlement. This mustbegin to change to implement <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor.Again we are talking about shades of capacity, notstark m<strong>on</strong>ochromatic differences. Am<strong>on</strong>g developingand transiti<strong>on</strong>al countries, those with highernati<strong>on</strong>al incomes tend to be recognised as havingthe str<strong>on</strong>ger administrative capability, though thereare certainly excepti<strong>on</strong>s to this pattern. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> leastdeveloped countries, especially small island nati<strong>on</strong>sand land-locked countries tend to have lowercapacity as a rule. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Pooris obviously easiest to carry out <strong>on</strong> a nati<strong>on</strong>al scalein countries with better capacity.State capacity is at its nadir in countries wherecentral authority is so ineffective that it has lost oris losing practical c<strong>on</strong>trol over much of its territory.Implementing <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor inthese political systems must be d<strong>on</strong>e entirely fromthe bottom up or the outside in, because the nati<strong>on</strong>algovernment is too dysfuncti<strong>on</strong>al to work from thetop down. C<strong>on</strong>sider the extreme case of Somalia,with four overlapping judicial structures: a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal<strong>on</strong>e in regi<strong>on</strong>al administrati<strong>on</strong>s and central governmentscreated at internati<strong>on</strong>al peace processes, atraditi<strong>on</strong>al, clan-based system, a growing numberof Muslim shari’a courts in urban areas, and ad hocmechanisms established by militias (Le Sage 2005:7). A nati<strong>on</strong>wide implementati<strong>on</strong> strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalempowerment is currently problematic in Somalia,though there may be local or regi<strong>on</strong>al space <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Box 5.3 Empowering <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ersthrough CommunityC<strong>on</strong>tracting‘As in many other places in Somalia, the civil war thathas been raging <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> years has had its toll <strong>on</strong> Garowe,a city in the Puntland regi<strong>on</strong> of that country. … A projectto improve the livelihoods of the people of Garowe throughsustainable waste collecti<strong>on</strong> management … applied theCommunity C<strong>on</strong>tracting Model, a participatory processwhereby the community group negotiates with local governmentor a development programmeme and enters intoc<strong>on</strong>tractual agreements to undertake garbage collecti<strong>on</strong>and disposal. This had multiple advantages: members ofthe community were directly involved in negotiating c<strong>on</strong>tractswhich in turn provided them with jobs that helpedthem improve their livelihoods.’‘This c<strong>on</strong>tracting system uses a participatory andbottom-up approach…. Local actors were resp<strong>on</strong>sible<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> … organising community c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s, transporthire, procurement of tools and materials, authorizati<strong>on</strong>of payments, decisi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> workers’ wages, selecti<strong>on</strong> andsupervisi<strong>on</strong> of workers and ensuring workers’ safety. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ywere also resp<strong>on</strong>sible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> solving all disputes related toproject implementati<strong>on</strong>.’‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a great potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> replicati<strong>on</strong> of sustainablewaste management activities in towns and municipalitieswithin the country as well as in urban centres ofother African countries.’ UN-Habitat, ILO and UNA (anItalian c<strong>on</strong>sortium of NGOs) have supported the Somaliinitiative.Indeed, 11 municipalities in Kenya, Tanzania and Ugandaare pursuing similar approaches to municipal service delivery.Community-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s, small enterprises,NGOs, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy operators and local traininginstituti<strong>on</strong>s work with the administrati<strong>on</strong> to create propoorurban services using public-private partnerships.This was made possible by changing local governmentby-laws. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> change opened up new opportunities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poormen and women; the ILO is working with local partnerstowards ensuring that the jobs are safe and productive.Source: ILO, Success Africa: Partnership <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> — ImprovingPeople’s Lives, 2nd vol. (Addis Ababa, Apr. 2007), pp. 2- 4 and31-33.301


e<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, as Box 5.3 indicates.Post-c<strong>on</strong>flict states present a special situati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment even if the central statehas nominally reasserted its claim to authority. Itis particularly vexing to figure out how to returnproperty after its rightful owners have fled or beenkilled by <strong>on</strong>e side or the other in a civil war. Oftenthe disputes over homes and other assets are sointense they must be addressed at <strong>on</strong>ce to sustainpeace. 6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> internati<strong>on</strong>al community has recognisedinstituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of the legal infrastructureis essential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rec<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> and rec<strong>on</strong>ciliati<strong>on</strong>.Yet, a realistic timeframe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> recreating a justicesystem following serious armed c<strong>on</strong>flict with <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malcourts, trained judges and a retrained police <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceis close to 20 years (Samuels 2006: 19). That is al<strong>on</strong>g period <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementati<strong>on</strong> with many chances<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrative operati<strong>on</strong> to deviate from initialpolicy intent.Merilee Grindle (2007) proposes an elementarytypology of political systems, adapted here in Table5.3, right, which is a useful place to begin to c<strong>on</strong>siderwhat sort of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorpolicies are feasible within different countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>three left-hand side column headings reflect thepolitical and administrative dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of regimes,with the far right-hand column very roughly indicatingthe sorts of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor initiativesthat might be appropriate; the rows are fivecomm<strong>on</strong> regime patterns or syndromes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se areheuristic, but they suggest the possibilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalempowerment are greatest in states that are morecompetitive and better instituti<strong>on</strong>alised. As Grindlepoints out, there is simply more to build up<strong>on</strong> inthese countries than in weaker states. A startingpoint <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor practiti<strong>on</strong>ers,then, is to debate h<strong>on</strong>estly where a particularcountry can be located am<strong>on</strong>g the comm<strong>on</strong> patternsof political administrative systems, and use thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> to think creatively but realistically aboutwhat empowering re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms will work in that c<strong>on</strong>text.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> typology in Table 5.3, right, is educative, notexhaustive; the capsule policy prescripti<strong>on</strong>s in thelast column <strong>on</strong> the right are not meant to cover allthe possibilities, which are too numerous to capturein a simple table. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reality <strong>on</strong> the ground is thatpolicy champi<strong>on</strong>s may need to pursue a variety oftactics in every country, custom fit to the differentstakeholders, to support their overall strategy.That means mobilising the grassroots, the communityorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, the professi<strong>on</strong>al groups, andother interests to counterbalance opp<strong>on</strong>ents of<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor trying to derail theagenda. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> prospect of working with state actorsvaries according to the administrative capacity ofthe government.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malityAcross-cutting dimensi<strong>on</strong> of the policy envir<strong>on</strong>mentis the extent of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality — in theec<strong>on</strong>omy, in the polity, and in the juridical system.People, organisati<strong>on</strong>s, and firms can operate underc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> some purposes andunder c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> others. <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers must besensitive to the vulnerability of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal empowermentmechanisms to cooptati<strong>on</strong> and dominati<strong>on</strong> byelites and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal organisati<strong>on</strong>s. Let us look at thephenomen<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>sider the impact <strong>on</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong>of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.In the ec<strong>on</strong>omic sense, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality refers to smallscale,self-financed and unskilled labour-intensiveproductive activities, which the poor use to survive.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se pursuits are under-the-table and off-thebooks,and thus are legally defenceless againstmore powerful market interests and are subject tounfair exploitati<strong>on</strong>. This parallel or shadow ec<strong>on</strong>omyis a vast domain, representing the equivalentof about 40 percent of official ec<strong>on</strong>omic activityin developing and transiti<strong>on</strong> countries, according302


Table 5.3. Political Administrative SyndromesPoliticalCompetiti<strong>on</strong>Instituti<strong>on</strong>alstability of the stateOrganisati<strong>on</strong>alcapacity of the statePotential <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor policyinitiatives*Nati<strong>on</strong>al level re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms inhuman and ec<strong>on</strong>omic rights;assert claims to existing legaland basic welfare services;work through established civilsocietyRule through stable andlegitimate organisati<strong>on</strong>sand procedures; opencompetiti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> powerthrough programmematicpartiesRules of the game widelyrecognized as legitimateand not subject tosignifi cant change; c<strong>on</strong>flictsresolved through appeal tothe rulesHigh. Organisati<strong>on</strong>schallenged to improveper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance <strong>on</strong> a sustainedbasis.Rule through stable andlegitimate organisati<strong>on</strong>sand procedures; no opencompetiti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> power.Political parties serve theregime or are hindered andc<strong>on</strong>trolled by itClear rules of the game andgenerally orderly processesof decisi<strong>on</strong>-making andpublic management are inplace; generally centralizedand authoritarian practices.Modest. Many organisati<strong>on</strong>scarry out routine activities<strong>on</strong> a sustained basis.Mobilisati<strong>on</strong> of poor citizens<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> greater influence over therange of legal protecti<strong>on</strong>s andopportunities from the centreAn unstable mixture ofpers<strong>on</strong>al and impers<strong>on</strong>alrule, with varying degreesof legitimacy. Partiesare based partly <strong>on</strong>pers<strong>on</strong>alitiesRule through pers<strong>on</strong>alitiesand pers<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s.If political partiesexist, they are based <strong>on</strong>pers<strong>on</strong>alities.Basic rules of the gameare established in lawand practice, althoughthey functi<strong>on</strong> poorly andintermittently.Low. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re may be someorganisati<strong>on</strong>s that are ableto carry out resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities<strong>on</strong> a sustained basis.Similar to above, but withpossibly more decentralisedfocus and more emphasis <strong>on</strong>instituti<strong>on</strong> building; corruptbureaucracy may be a biggerobstacleBypass strategies to get aroundcorrupt officials; incrementalsteps <strong>on</strong>ly; watch out <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> elitecaptureStability highly dependent<strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>trol ofpower. Rules of the gameemphasise power of elitesand pers<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s toelites; there is c<strong>on</strong>fl ict overwho c<strong>on</strong>trols the stateLow. Organisati<strong>on</strong>s resp<strong>on</strong>dto the pers<strong>on</strong>al and shiftingpriorities of powerful elites.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no effective centralgovernmentExtremely low. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are noeffective rules of the gamethat are agreed up<strong>on</strong>Extremely low. It is difficultto identify organisati<strong>on</strong>sthat have any capacity toproduce results.Community-basedempowerment programmemes* Illustrative examples <strong>on</strong>ly; the activities in these cells are not mutually exclusive.to a study financed by the World Bank (Schneider2002). Half or more of the employment (includingsubsistence farming) in developing countriesis outside the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector. Earnings are low anduncertain, but these parallel market activities haveproven remarkably vital and have grown worldwidein new guises and unexpected places. Capturingthe positive attributes of the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omywhile minimising the low productivity and hazardousworking c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that go al<strong>on</strong>g with it, is<strong>on</strong>e of the challenges of the legal empowermentagenda.Ec<strong>on</strong>omic in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality does have some advantages<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor; <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, women may find home-303


ased work easier to fit in around their householdresp<strong>on</strong>sibilities. Formal sector businesses maychoose to outsource work to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal workers togain flexibility. That said, these jobs are mostlyvery badly paid, often dangerous, and they relyheavily <strong>on</strong> children (ILO 2003). Most people whotoil in the parallel ec<strong>on</strong>omy do so out of necessity,not freely exercised choice. Judith Tendler (2002)writes of an implicit ‘devil’s deal’ in Brazil and othercountries, whereby in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy workers andentrepreneurs c<strong>on</strong>sent to support certain politicians.In return, the politicians agree not to en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce tax,envir<strong>on</strong>mental, or labour regulati<strong>on</strong>s; and to keepthe police and inspectors from harassing the poor.This arrangement is difficult <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> either side to getout of and it limits the opti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment.Tendler suggests the way to break the ‘devil’sdeal’ is by dem<strong>on</strong>strating the paths by which smallfirms grow into <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m <strong>on</strong>es, including treating workersbetter and helping to upgrade their skills.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> boundary between the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omies is fluid and poor people can push it in adirecti<strong>on</strong> that favours them. Cairo, to take an example,has an in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal refuse collecti<strong>on</strong> system whichactually has a well-defined set of internal rights,resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities, and sancti<strong>on</strong>s that evolved overseveral decades in resp<strong>on</strong>se to a changing externalenvir<strong>on</strong>ment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> city tried to bring refuse collecti<strong>on</strong>under municipal c<strong>on</strong>trol by issuing licenses to largecorporate c<strong>on</strong>tractors. Refuse collecti<strong>on</strong> is a majorenterprise <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people so the city was threateningtheir livelihood. After negotiati<strong>on</strong> and mutualadjustment, a new arrangement emerged in whichsmall-scale service providers selectively adoptedinstituti<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms recognised by the municipalauthorities, while hanging <strong>on</strong> to the pers<strong>on</strong>alisedand adaptable practices that marked their in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malsystem (Assaad 1996). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d element ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality that c<strong>on</strong>cerns <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor policy implementati<strong>on</strong> is found in the politicalsystem. Similar to what goes <strong>on</strong> in the ec<strong>on</strong>omy,in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality here is based <strong>on</strong> implicit and unwrittenunderstandings. In effect, it is a coping method <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> terms used to describe this grey governmentz<strong>on</strong>e are ‘patrim<strong>on</strong>ialism’ and ‘clientelism.’Its dimensi<strong>on</strong>s are hard to measure, but the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malpatr<strong>on</strong>-client political system is widespread inmany countries and may crowd out the official statesystem of rule, al<strong>on</strong>g with that system’s broad policiesthat guarantee rights and distribute privilegesaccording to objective criteria.Patr<strong>on</strong>-client politics emerge from webs ofpers<strong>on</strong>al b<strong>on</strong>ds that develop between patr<strong>on</strong>sand their individual clients or followers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seb<strong>on</strong>ds are founded <strong>on</strong> mutual material advantage:the patr<strong>on</strong> furnishes excludable resources (m<strong>on</strong>ey,jobs) in return <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> support and cooperati<strong>on</strong> (votes,attendance at rallies). Typically, marginalizedmembers of society are drawn into patr<strong>on</strong>-clientarrangements as a more reliable means thanthe state to take care of their everyday c<strong>on</strong>cerns(Brinkerhoff and Goldsmith 2004). Clientelismis widely seen as a barrier to more transparentgovernance and professi<strong>on</strong>al public administrati<strong>on</strong>.It lives <strong>on</strong>, however, because it provides somethingof value to people. No society is so ‘advanced’ thatit relies exclusively <strong>on</strong> de jure instituti<strong>on</strong>s to run itscomm<strong>on</strong> affairs. For all their drawbacks, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malpatr<strong>on</strong>-client exchanges are expedient means to getthings d<strong>on</strong>e.Clientelism evolves and adapts to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malgovernance system, similar to what happens in theec<strong>on</strong>omic sphere. In fact, individuals who holdthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal levers of power are often also head uppatr<strong>on</strong>age networks. Political openness, widespreadpolitical participati<strong>on</strong> and the emergence of broadprogrammeme that help people regardless of theirpers<strong>on</strong>al affiliati<strong>on</strong>s are ways ‘clientelism’ can bepushed back to benefit the poor (Brinkerhoff andGoldsmith 2005). But this is a struggle. Patr<strong>on</strong>s do304


not give up their positi<strong>on</strong> willingly, and they oftenhave multiple additi<strong>on</strong>al claims to power, not justtheir c<strong>on</strong>trol over material resources but also legitimacyderived from a high positi<strong>on</strong> in the local systemof social stratificati<strong>on</strong> and privilege. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re maybe a religiously or historically derived c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> ofdeference to authority that makes poor people lesslikely to stand up <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their prescribed rights againstthe wishes of traditi<strong>on</strong>al patr<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> participatory budget process in Porto Alegre,Brazil illustrates how hardy ‘‘clientelism’’ canbe. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> city has garnered a great deal of attenti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> making public spending more programmematicand universal, and less dependent <strong>on</strong> individualc<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s and friends in high places. When the<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers Party came to power in Porto Alegre in1989, it was determined to end the ‘clientelism’ ofthe old administrati<strong>on</strong> and it set up an inclusive processthat involved citizens from all social groups inestablishing budget priorities, allocating investmentsand m<strong>on</strong>itoring results. Many city council representativesheld office based <strong>on</strong> clientelistic networkstied to neighbourhood associati<strong>on</strong>s. Though oftendisagreeing with participatory budgeting, they voted<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> it with the hope of using the programmeme’spopularity to gain votes in the next electi<strong>on</strong>. It wasdifficult <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> these legislators to oppose projects thatdirectly benefited their own c<strong>on</strong>stituents (Wampler2007). Despite this progress, after the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ersParty lost c<strong>on</strong>trol of the city government in 2004,due in part to a drop in support from its low-incomepolitical base, there were signs of resurgent ‘clientelism’,with the city councillors and municipal staff<strong>on</strong>ce again doing deals to arrange individualiseddelivery of public works and services.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality turns up a third time in the legalsystem itself, where we again see overlappingstatutory and n<strong>on</strong>-state systems of law (includingmafia-like self-regulating systems) in everycountry. As with ec<strong>on</strong>omic in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and political‘clientelism’, the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal structures existpartly because they are more accessible and ‘userfriendly’ to people of limited means. Sometimes,private or mixed arrangements <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rule en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementand settlement are efficient because they enjoythe c<strong>on</strong>fidence of the participants and encourageflexibility and compromise within communitynorms. Other times, however, the n<strong>on</strong>-state systemis neither efficient nor fair.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> minibus-taxi industry in South Africa shows howthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omic and governance domainscan coincide in the real world, in this instance withmajor social cost. Minibuses are the major means oftransportati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> South Africa’s poor, plus a majorsource of employment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people. A loophole inthe transit law allowed this largely unregulated sectorto emerge toward the end of the apartheid era,and commuter transportati<strong>on</strong> became dominatedby independent small, business operators, drivingowned or rented vehicles. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> minibus-taxi businessprovided low-cost movement around the country ata time when the majority was trying to get out fromunder the oppressive minority regime ruling SouthAfrica, and it has c<strong>on</strong>tinued to grow to currentlyaccount <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> about two-thirds of commuter travel.In the absence of government regulati<strong>on</strong>, however,the individual minibus owners and drivers turned toemerging private industry associati<strong>on</strong>s to allocatetaxi routes and cab stands, and to settle disputesthat arose am<strong>on</strong>g competitors. Over time, these associati<strong>on</strong>sgrew very powerful in their own right andbegan to use str<strong>on</strong>g-arm tactics to defend or expandturf claimed by rival taxi groups. By the mid-1990sa virtual taxi war was costing hundred of drivers andpassengers their lives each year. Lack of vehiclemaintenance, overloading and poor safety standardsled to thousands of additi<strong>on</strong>al fatalities per year inroad accidents. According to reports, the police havebeen corrupted to look the other way <strong>on</strong> traffic violati<strong>on</strong>sand in some cases have become leaders in the305


Box 5.4 Organising out ofPoverty: Taxis in Rwanda<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Cooperatives Alliance, the Internati<strong>on</strong>alTrade Uni<strong>on</strong> C<strong>on</strong>federati<strong>on</strong> (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>merly theICFTU) and the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour Organisati<strong>on</strong>have teamed up to develop an approach known asSYNDICOOP. ‘SYNDICOOP promotes trade uni<strong>on</strong>s andcooperatives — membership-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>workers in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy. And because theyare membership organisati<strong>on</strong>s, they can be accountable.’An example is Assetamorwa (Associati<strong>on</strong> del’Esperance des Taxis Moto au Rwanda) inRwanda. ‘Each driver is an individual trader, negotiatingfares with passengers. But by combining together,they support each other and can negotiate with theauthorities of Kigali, the Rwandan capital.’ Assetamorwahas organised a system of pooling m<strong>on</strong>eythat its members can tap in turn (known as t<strong>on</strong>tine)and a health insurance fund <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> members. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> groupalso trains young drivers, runs a garage and sparepartsdepot, and works to combat the spread ofHIV/AIDS. All of this activity depends <strong>on</strong> the necessaryframework legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> andcooperatives being in place at the nati<strong>on</strong>al level.Source: Stirling Smith and Cilla Ross, Organising out of poverty:Stories from the grassroots: How the SYNDICOOP approach hasworked in East Africa (Co-operative College, Oldham, 2006).violence and intimidati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g taxi associati<strong>on</strong>s(Barrett 2003).Fortunately, freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> is guaranteedby law in South Africa, and the governmenthas a n<strong>on</strong>-judicial mechanism to resolvedisputes through mediati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>ciliati<strong>on</strong>. Thus,instituti<strong>on</strong>al and legal c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s exist <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> overcomingthe industry’s problems. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government hastried to reassert its regulatory authority and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malizethe industry. After c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with stakeholders,a financial incentive programmeme has beendeveloped to encourage operators to upgrade theminibus fleet, join designated membership associati<strong>on</strong>s,keep better records and begin payingtaxes <strong>on</strong> their enterprises (van der Merwe 2007).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> effectiveness of these ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to supplant thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s and practices remains to beproven, however.This example is extreme, and Box 5.4 reports amuch more encouraging case of a taxi drivers’organisati<strong>on</strong> from Africa; nevertheless, it makes thepoint that development practiti<strong>on</strong>ers face dilemmasin dealing with in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality (and, by extensi<strong>on</strong>,with decentralised and local instituti<strong>on</strong>s generally).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are obvious advantages to exercising rightsthrough pers<strong>on</strong>alized and traditi<strong>on</strong>al authority becauseit is less expensive, more familiar and locallyavailable. Yet, just because de facto or relati<strong>on</strong>ship-basedauthority is embedded in poor communitiesdoes not mean they must be c<strong>on</strong>structivein fighting poverty and injustice, as the violentfeuding of the South African taxi case vividly illustrates.A patr<strong>on</strong>-client network, or clique, mayprovide a safe haven <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> society’s most vulnerable,but it limits their opti<strong>on</strong>s also, l<strong>on</strong>g-establishedrules <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> allocating resources may work when thepopulati<strong>on</strong> is small, but they might buckle underpopulati<strong>on</strong> pressure. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, a private legalmechanism may be accessible, but it could easilyplay favourites depending <strong>on</strong> a plaintiff’s pers<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s.A bottom-line c<strong>on</strong>cern is that development professi<strong>on</strong>alsmust creatively seek to capitalise <strong>on</strong> theavailable mix of de facto or ‘traditi<strong>on</strong>al’ modes ofauthority. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is no reas<strong>on</strong> to assume that thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s, rules and arrangements areeither superior or inferior to their de jure or ‘modern’counterparts. C<strong>on</strong>text is critical. India is a possiblemodel <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> how to integrate representative andlegal instituti<strong>on</strong>s, having extended official recogniti<strong>on</strong>to a system of village councils and people’s306


Box 5.5 Authority Systems: Land RightsRegarding the critical asset of land, there exists aninternati<strong>on</strong>ally well recognized spectrum of rights, asshown in the figure below. Starting with the floor offreedom from evicti<strong>on</strong>, security of tenure progressivelyimproves as <strong>on</strong>e follows the arrow. Land rights begin withthe percepti<strong>on</strong> that <strong>on</strong>e will not be evicted, based often<strong>on</strong> political statements to that effect. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> right becomesstr<strong>on</strong>ger through customary law, temporary occupancycertifi cates, through anti-evicti<strong>on</strong> legislati<strong>on</strong> and adversepossessi<strong>on</strong> (otherwise known as squatters’ rights) andgroup tenure. L<strong>on</strong>g-term leases and individual freeholdtenure represent the most secure <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of tenure. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>noteworthy feature of the c<strong>on</strong>tinuum of land rights isthat it accommodates and reflects the diverse realityof land rights and social land tenures that exist in theworld today (<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, family and group rights). It alsodem<strong>on</strong>strates the potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an incremental path togreater security c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the way the poor accumulatetheir resources over time. This approach may be asolid foundati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> achieving c<strong>on</strong>sensus <strong>on</strong> the issue ofland and property rights. It is also a good starting point<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> developing an innovative spectrum of protecti<strong>on</strong> andopportunities in this area, where parallel opportunitiesprotecti<strong>on</strong>/securityspectrums can also be linked (e.g.labour, justice, entrepreneurship).C<strong>on</strong>tinuum of Rights<strong>Legal</strong> or<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal rightsCustomaryPerceived tenure approaches:• Political statements• Services without legal tenureAnti evicti<strong>on</strong>sOccupancyLeasesGroup tenureAdverse possessi<strong>on</strong>RegisteredfreeholdIllegal orin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal rightscourts. Drawing <strong>on</strong> traditi<strong>on</strong>al norms, the councilsare reported to be seeking out new roles and tobe adapting to the democratic factor in India’s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal political instituti<strong>on</strong>s (Pur and Moore 2007).Several West African countries use decentralisedlocal councils to administer land laws. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>setend to be based <strong>on</strong> customary power structures,though as yet they appear upwardly accountable tothe central state, rather than downwardly to localpopulati<strong>on</strong>s (Ribot 1999). Box 5.5 discusses howthe integrati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality mayhelp the poor with land rights generally.In all instances poor people’s percepti<strong>on</strong>s shouldbe kept fr<strong>on</strong>t and centre. <strong>Legal</strong> or organisati<strong>on</strong>alre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that look self-evidently empowering toexperts from outside the poor community may lookdangerous from the perspective of some<strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> theinside. This could detract from the local supportneeded <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementati<strong>on</strong>.’As we finish this aspect of Secti<strong>on</strong> 2, it should bemore than evident how important c<strong>on</strong>textual analysisis to implementati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Policy makers have to come togrips with the nati<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment of public policy— that is, with the domestic social structure, ec<strong>on</strong>omicc<strong>on</strong>text, nature of the political and administrativesystems, and the scale of ec<strong>on</strong>omic andlegal in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality. While a country’s envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m has to be unpacked and probed <strong>on</strong> its ownterms, we have offered useful questi<strong>on</strong>s that couldbe asked. Practiti<strong>on</strong>ers and policymakers can makegood use of the tool of c<strong>on</strong>textual analysis to determineif c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s appear ripe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, which implementati<strong>on</strong>scenarios seem most probable, what sequencingand timelines <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m look doable and how they307


should be designed, what tradeoffs need to bec<strong>on</strong>sidered, which risk mitigating mechanisms areworth trying, and what c<strong>on</strong>textual variables needcareful m<strong>on</strong>itoring during implementati<strong>on</strong>. Adheringto this general set of guidelines will increasethe chances of successfully carrying out empowermentpolicies.Policy characteristicsThree internal policy characteristics (the lowermiddle box in Figure 5.2, above) stand out ininfluencing implementati<strong>on</strong>: complexity, ambiguityand the potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> discord and c<strong>on</strong>flict. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>secharacteristics are important in all policy arenas butare especially relevant <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the four domains of legalempowerment.ComplexityOther things being equal, the more complex a policyis, the harder it is to implement due to the intensityof the administrative ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t required. On the scale ofcomplexity, <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor tendsto fall at the far end. As seen by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>,the paradigm <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment is holistic and thushighly ambitious. Ideally, the poor should obtainlegal protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their physical and financialassets (property rights) and human capital (labourrights), and also have the ability to engage in markettransacti<strong>on</strong>s (business rights). Cutting across allthree areas is a need to obtain access to justiceand political decisi<strong>on</strong> making (legal identity andcitizenship rights). Those are a lot of balls to juggleduring implementati<strong>on</strong>. It may be best to go <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>wardselectively and not dissipate energy <strong>on</strong> too many initiativesat <strong>on</strong>ce. On the other hand, progress in <strong>on</strong>ly<strong>on</strong>e area without the others may create imbalancesthat perpetuate poverty.A sec<strong>on</strong>d source of complexity is the fact that legaland regulatory systems are very robust; meaningthat rec<strong>on</strong>figurati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>on</strong>e or a few aspects of thelaw or instituti<strong>on</strong>s may not alter the overall risk andlack of opportunity poor people face. Social c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>sand structures develop over l<strong>on</strong>g periodswith many redundancies and mutually rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cingelements. Progress in <strong>on</strong>e domain of empowermentmay be neutralised by lack of progress in another.Unanticipated effects may also be triggered duringimplementati<strong>on</strong> that undermine or bypass theintended beneficiaries. In Peru, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance, the introducti<strong>on</strong>of greater flexibility in the labour marketwas heralded as progress in the early to mid 1990s;<strong>on</strong>e of its effects, however, was to drastically reducethe percentage of the populati<strong>on</strong> who enjoyed alegal status as employees, which had given themaccess to social protecti<strong>on</strong>. Poverty rates increasedin the short-term. Had the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m package beenless sweeping, or accompanied by a social floor ormitigating measures, this negative impact mighthave been avoided.Third is the time dimensi<strong>on</strong> to complexity. Empowermentpolicies seldom take effect quickly. Regardinglaw re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m to promote the right to freedom ofassociati<strong>on</strong> and collective bargaining, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance,the ILO (2004: 110-111) has observed that fourto five years is the minimum time that should beallowed be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e substantive results can be seen. Ingeneral, delays make political back-tracking likely asministerial appointments change and bring in newministers who have little interest or commitmentto their predecessor’s programmemes. Hesitati<strong>on</strong>in implementati<strong>on</strong> rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces any inclinati<strong>on</strong> of thepoor not to go al<strong>on</strong>g as expected with a policy in thefirst place. Individual uncertainty about implementati<strong>on</strong>encourages the majority to hold back supportingthe re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, which creates a self-fulfilling prophecyof implementati<strong>on</strong> slippage. Thus it is importantto look <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> interventi<strong>on</strong>s that promise short-termrewards <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> beneficiaries. Micro-finance, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example,can have an immediate (though perhaps notsustainable) effect <strong>on</strong> poor people’s c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>.308


Afinal source of complexity is that legal empowermentis both a top-down activity (initiativeand coordinati<strong>on</strong> often come from the nati<strong>on</strong>alcapital, regi<strong>on</strong>al centre, or city hall) and a bottomupactivity (the poor and their allies play a centralrole as advocates and watchdogs). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are manychances <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> misunderstanding and miscommunicati<strong>on</strong>with a policy where leadership comes fromseveral directi<strong>on</strong>s. Even if NGOs and local communitiesare the prime movers of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor, they may not be able to accomplishmuch <strong>on</strong> their own without government assistance.An example of how complexity can distort implementati<strong>on</strong>of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor isthe <strong>on</strong>going struggle over labour rights in LatinAmerica. During the 1990s, several governmentsin the regi<strong>on</strong> tried to promote greater flexibilityin the labour market through changes in nati<strong>on</strong>allabour legislati<strong>on</strong>. This undermined labour uni<strong>on</strong>members’ freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> and rights tocollective bargaining; it also impinged <strong>on</strong> workersas individuals because they lost job security. Tradeuni<strong>on</strong>s fought back against these changes and, insome cases, succeeded in curbing erosi<strong>on</strong> of theirgroup rights, a positive accomplishment from theperspective of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. Butthey often ceded <strong>on</strong> deregulati<strong>on</strong> of employmentlaw relating to individual rights, which is perhapsan even greater loss <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> an <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor agenda. An unintended by product ofthese policy disputes was also to strengthen thelarger and more established uni<strong>on</strong>s but to furtherweaken the organising and bargaining rights ofemerging rival uni<strong>on</strong>s (Cook 2005). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se last areoften str<strong>on</strong>g allies of poor people.AmbiguityAmbiguous policies are also more challenging tocarry out than clear policies are. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are severalreas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> this, but a principal <strong>on</strong>e is that ambiguitygives bureaucratic stakeholders greater discreti<strong>on</strong>in interpreting or even ignoring the policy.Ambiguity also clouds the ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts of beneficiariesand sp<strong>on</strong>sor groups to hold the bureaucrats toaccount. As a result, the policy in practice tendsto drift further and further away from its design.Many policies related to <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor rank relatively high <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ambiguity. In severalAfrican countries, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, local people’s accessto land is protected through use rights, whichare legally recognised as l<strong>on</strong>g as the land is put toproductive use. What uses are ‘productive’ is notclear in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal law, however, which tends tofavour large-scale commercial or industrial usersnot pastoralist or subsistence farmers seeking accessto land (Cotula 2007: 36). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> less clear-cuta policy is, generally the greater is the probabilityof elite capture during implementati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal arrangements discussed earlierare a source of ambiguity simply because they existside by side with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal system of civil andcriminal justice. Which <strong>on</strong>e takes precedence? <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>inadvertent result could be a labyrinth of law, inwhich the poor and disadvantaged may lose theirway. Setting aside any possible net advantages ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor in a given legal c<strong>on</strong>text, theabsence of documentati<strong>on</strong> tends to render in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maljustice a less effective plat<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementingempowerment strategies. C<strong>on</strong>sider the phenomen<strong>on</strong>known as ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um shopping’ whereby ec<strong>on</strong>omicactors navigate am<strong>on</strong>g multiple legal orders to seekthe most favourable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um to pursue their claims.Thus a policy to give legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> to poorpeople’s customary system of justice or disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong> may in some cases work against thepoor, as l<strong>on</strong>g as the statutory or rule-based legalcode c<strong>on</strong>tinues to exist. A business corporati<strong>on</strong> orrich pers<strong>on</strong> will simply avoid the less expensivetraditi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce poor people to litigatein <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ums where they are at a disadvantage. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>309


flip side of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um shopping is that NGOs and humanrights stakeholder groups working <strong>on</strong> behalf ofthe poor also have multiple venues to seek redressof their grievances, so, again, the implicati<strong>on</strong> isnot that instituti<strong>on</strong>al pluralism is inherently bad <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. Still, it is a complicatingfactor that makes empowerment policiestrickier to plan and execute.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re may be temptati<strong>on</strong> to clarify anambiguous in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal structure simplyby replacing it with a more orderly statutory code,but as it might c<strong>on</strong>ceivably backfire <strong>on</strong> the poor,any approach must be carefully reas<strong>on</strong>ed. Sudanis an acute case of what can happen when changeis suddenly rushed though. Urban elites in Sudanaggressively moved to take land at less than itstrue value by shifting land out of community-basedtenure systems and into a standardised Islamictenure system. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil war that raged <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> years inthe south of the country was set in moti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> manyreas<strong>on</strong>s, but <strong>on</strong>e was the resistance by rural peopleto the impositi<strong>on</strong> of an unfamiliar tenure systemthat destroyed their traditi<strong>on</strong>al land rights (Bruceet al. 1998: 195). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>flict in Sudan’s Darfurregi<strong>on</strong> also grows in part out of c<strong>on</strong>flicts aroundcompeting systems of land tenure, representedby group-based camel nomadism, <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>ehand, and more individually oriented sedentarycultivati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong> the other (Abdul-Jalil 2005).Ambiguity additi<strong>on</strong>ally clouds lines of accountabilityand resp<strong>on</strong>sibility am<strong>on</strong>g implementing agenciesand allows them to ‘pass the buck’ during implementati<strong>on</strong>.In post-tsunami Sri Lanka, the housingauthority allocated land to the displaced which waslater found to have been under claim by the municipalityas a waste dump, and had been classifiedby the water board as uninhabitable. Straighteningout mix-ups like this takes time and energy thatcould have been used more productively.Discord<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> distributi<strong>on</strong>al strife unearthed by policy ambiguityin countries such as Sudan merges into thethird stylised internal influence <strong>on</strong> implementati<strong>on</strong>,which is a policy’s inbuilt potential to generatedissensi<strong>on</strong>. An ‘ir<strong>on</strong> law of public policy’ saysthat most acts of government, no matter what thebroader merits, create winners and losers. If thegains and losses are seen as significant, they willbecome the object of intense political attenti<strong>on</strong>.This is particularly likely where the policy redistributesa right or benefit from <strong>on</strong>e group to another,as happens when there are mutually exclusiveclaims to a fixed resource such as fertile land orminerals. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor attemptsto minimise redistributive c<strong>on</strong>flicts by expandingec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunities so that different interestscan be negotiated to meet every side’s needs, butthere is still plenty of potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong>because important stakeholders believe others’gains come at their expense. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mutual payoff tolegal empowerment is in the future, but the individualsacrifices must be borne now.A c<strong>on</strong>crete example of this ‘ir<strong>on</strong> law’ is the titlingand registrati<strong>on</strong> programmeme implemented in Perustarting in the 1980s. According to a World Bankreport, the main winners were: settlers, who accruedthe ec<strong>on</strong>omic and social benefits of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ownership;the President of Peru, who earned the politicalcredit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the programmeme; local mayors, whoshared the political credit, and c<strong>on</strong>gressmen, whobacked the legal framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malizati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>principal losers were reportedly the public officialsin charge of regularisati<strong>on</strong> processes who previouslybenefited from bribes; lawyers and notaries, who lostthe m<strong>on</strong>opoly they enjoyed in the traditi<strong>on</strong>al registrati<strong>on</strong>system, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer community leaders, whowere replaced by new leaders elected by the communitiesduring the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms (Palacio 2006: 41).In c<strong>on</strong>flict equati<strong>on</strong>s, defenders of the status quo310


almost always have the upper hand because theyhave w<strong>on</strong> earlier power struggles over the samepublic policies. With <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor a special difficulty is that the self-perceived‘losers’ are apt to include members of the local eliteand bureaucrats menti<strong>on</strong>ed earlier, who feel theirm<strong>on</strong>opoly <strong>on</strong> neighbourhood or community power isjeopardised should any<strong>on</strong>e else gain ec<strong>on</strong>omic andfinancial independence. While these stakeholdershave many means to delay or dilute implementati<strong>on</strong>of policies they reject — especially by co-opting thepoor through the dependency relati<strong>on</strong>ships of patr<strong>on</strong>ageand ‘clientelism’ and by corrupting the localbureaucracy — the example of Peru proves it is possibleto overcome the odds with the right leadershipand a winning coaliti<strong>on</strong> of support.<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor c<strong>on</strong>flicts canbe mapped and c<strong>on</strong>sidered be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e they come toa head, providing time to think about politicalstrategies to manage the tensi<strong>on</strong>. A policy’s costand benefit can both be widely distributed (spreadover most citizens) or narrowly focused (limited toan identifiable group). Decisi<strong>on</strong>s by a central bankto greatly expand the m<strong>on</strong>ey supply, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance,have widely distributed costs because every<strong>on</strong>ehas to pay the c<strong>on</strong>sequent inflated prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> goodsand services. Regulati<strong>on</strong>s targeting a specificindustry, such as licensing or safety inspecti<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> minicab taxis (menti<strong>on</strong>ed earlier), are morefocused and narrowly c<strong>on</strong>centrated and may beperceived as a loss or gain <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> those most affected.In other words, whether people see themselves aspolicy winners or losers is more important than thereality of who wins or loses. By and large, we cangroup the varieties of political situati<strong>on</strong>s into fourcategories; they are shown in Figure 5.3. 7 Each hasdifferent implicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> generating c<strong>on</strong>flict.Figure 5.3 C<strong>on</strong>flict Implicati<strong>on</strong>s of Public PolicyPerceived policy costdispersed c<strong>on</strong>centratedPerceived policy benefitnarrowWinner takes all(high c<strong>on</strong>flict due tozero-sumcompetiti<strong>on</strong>)Patr<strong>on</strong>-clientpolitics/corrupti<strong>on</strong>(stable, low c<strong>on</strong>flictbecause costs arehidden andbeneficiaries havelittle inducement tochange)wideCollective Inacti<strong>on</strong>(little incentive <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>beneficiaries tomobilize; str<strong>on</strong>gincentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>victims to react) –Need policyentrepreneursC<strong>on</strong>sensus politics(low c<strong>on</strong>flict due toapparent positive –sum gains)<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor policies such asland titling or legal assistance fall in the top twocells in this matrix. Where both cost and benefitare narrowly c<strong>on</strong>centrated (the top left cell),each side has an incentive to dig in to defend itsinterests by preventing or establishing the transferof resources. Because the policy affects relativelyfew people, gaining allies may be difficult <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> bothsides unless they can make ‘side payments’ orengage in ‘logrolling’. 8 Where the benefit is widelydispersed, as might be true of many policies designedto help the poor by expanding their rights,getting those beneficiaries motivated to push <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the policy is difficult because the individual gainsare small or may seem abstract. In short, eachcategory of policies tends to have a distinct shapethat <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor practiti<strong>on</strong>ersought to be alert to, as they try to predict and influencestakeholder acti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> categories, however,are not air-tight and can metamorphose into <strong>on</strong>eanother over time, as percepti<strong>on</strong>s of issues change.Thus educati<strong>on</strong> and marketing are importantaspects of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor implementati<strong>on</strong>to try to get stakeholders to take a widerperspective <strong>on</strong> their self-interest.311


Less<strong>on</strong>s may be drawn from knowledge about theinbuilt characteristics of public policy. For example,as <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor tendsto be complex and ambiguous, and as implementati<strong>on</strong>ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts might there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e be hindered, thepolicies to promote empowerment must be madeas clear-cut and straight<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward as possible. Designsimplicity is <strong>on</strong>e way to avoid or minimise c<strong>on</strong>flict,uncertainty and other implementati<strong>on</strong> problemsarising from procedural and technical traits of legalempowerment activities.Diagnosing the Influence <strong>on</strong> PolicyImplementati<strong>on</strong>We have emphasised the stresses and strains <strong>on</strong><strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor implementati<strong>on</strong>to awaken policymakers to the need to think pragmaticallyand opportunistically about policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.Policymaking is not an assembly line, and a <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulaicapproach to the ‘who’, ‘what’ and ‘where’ factorscould lead to overly pessimistic generalisati<strong>on</strong>s andmissed opportunities. Effective implementati<strong>on</strong>requires a mix of experience, professi<strong>on</strong>al judgment,and a willingness to take chances. Creativeactors look <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy windows that open up andcreate space <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> moving <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward to solve a particularproblem, even when the circumstances appear to bedifficult.With these caveats in mind, Table 5.4 outlineshow to catalogue the influential factors in differentnati<strong>on</strong>s and assess tendencies to impel orimpede implementati<strong>on</strong> (as indicated by the threeright-hand columns). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong>s are illustrativeand need to be altered to suit different needs andsituati<strong>on</strong>s.An approach to implementati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Country ‘X’Broadly, <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor implementati<strong>on</strong>in country ‘X’ might start with an envir<strong>on</strong>mentalscan and c<strong>on</strong>textual analysis. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> focuswould be <strong>on</strong> 1) social and cultural features thataffect implementati<strong>on</strong>; 2) the ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>text,which also can be both a help and a hindrance,and 3) <strong>on</strong> the openness and capacity of the state.Supplementing the inventory of these c<strong>on</strong>cernswould be a careful analysis of the reach and holdthat in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s have <strong>on</strong> the poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>full c<strong>on</strong>textual analysis would then <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the basis<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a feasibility review of various empowermentscenarios.Next (or perhaps simultaneously because these arenever discrete implementati<strong>on</strong> steps), local activistsand external change agents in country ‘X’ would undertakea stakeholder analysis of the c<strong>on</strong>stituenciesc<strong>on</strong>cerned with <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> objective: to differentiate am<strong>on</strong>g the superficiallyhomogeneous beneficiaries, to better understandthe divisi<strong>on</strong>s, alliances and particular needsthat exist am<strong>on</strong>g the poor. Other stakeholders, whomight oppose or assist the target group or groups,would also be scrutinised to see what motivatestheir behaviour and reflect <strong>on</strong> how they could bebrought into the process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> purpose of the stakeholderanalysis would be to get a firmer grasp ofthe probability of moving <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward with various <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor scenarios, and to beginserious thinking about what it might take to build aminimum winning coaliti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowermentin country ‘X’.Finally, with possible overlapping chr<strong>on</strong>ology, theinternal technical features of the alternative policyscenarios would be reviewed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy characteristicsanalysis would focus <strong>on</strong> the complexitiesof the various policies, potential ambiguities thatmight possibly sow discord — all of which wouldserve to hinder implementati<strong>on</strong>. Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts would bemade to find a simple, incremental and sustainablecourse of acti<strong>on</strong>, and to avoid as much as possibletaking steps that provoke c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong> needlessly312


Table 5.4 Skelet<strong>on</strong> Diagnostic Tool:Analysing Influences <strong>on</strong> Policy Implementati<strong>on</strong>Questi<strong>on</strong>s (list is not comprehensive)Effect <strong>on</strong> Implementati<strong>on</strong>Negative Positive NeutralPolicy Envir<strong>on</strong>mentHow extensive are poverty and lack of ownership of or access to productive assets?What is the positi<strong>on</strong> of women in society?What is the degree of social and ethnic heterogeneity? Are there marginalizedminorities?What is the relative balance of power am<strong>on</strong>g social/ethnic groups?What dependency relati<strong>on</strong>s exist between elites and the poor?How open and competitive is the political system? Nati<strong>on</strong>ally? Locally?Is freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> guaranteed?To what extent do public agencies operate as effective bureaucracies? Is bureaucraticcorrupti<strong>on</strong> comm<strong>on</strong>?What is the capacity of instituti<strong>on</strong>s of the state to deal with the agenda of legalempowerment? Are accountabilities clearly spelled out?How scarce or abundant are government resources?Anything special about the country c<strong>on</strong>text? (Transiti<strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omy, least developedcountry, post-c<strong>on</strong>fl ict, etc.)Policy StakeholdersWho are the target benefi ciaries? How many are there? Are they members of an ethnicgroup or groups? Mostly women?Are the beneficiaries organised?What civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s exist? Where do they stand <strong>on</strong> the pro-poor policyissue?Who is in oppositi<strong>on</strong> to the policy? What are their resources?What allies and potential allies are there <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowering the poor?Policy CharacteristicsHow complex are the changes that are supposed to happen? Are these small departuresfrom current practices or major changes?Is the policy geographically c<strong>on</strong>centrated?Does it require a high degree of technical or professi<strong>on</strong>al knowledge?What is the level of c<strong>on</strong>fl ict about the value and nature of the changes?What does the pro-poor policy do? Is this clear or vague?What is the desired impact of policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, what is it expected to accomplish orfacilitate?313


Table 5.4 Skelet<strong>on</strong> Diagnostic Tool:Analysing Influences <strong>on</strong> Policy Implementati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>t.Questi<strong>on</strong>s (list is not comprehensive)Effect <strong>on</strong> Implementati<strong>on</strong>Negative Positive NeutralPolicy Characteristics c<strong>on</strong>t.Where did the impetus <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the policy come from?Who decided to pursue the policy, how, and why?What is the nature of the policy benefi ts, and to whom do they accrue (disaggregated bysex, age and ethnicity)?What is the nature of the costs of the policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, and who bears them(disaggregated by sex, age and ethnicity)?What is the degree and complexity of the changes brought about by the new policy?How administratively intense or technically complex is the new policy?— recognising that some c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong> is unavoidableand that it might even prove productive inmoving the empowerment agenda <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward. Obviously,what <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> works <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor in country ‘X’ may be irrelevant in country‘Y’ with a very different social structure, ec<strong>on</strong>omicenvir<strong>on</strong>ment and universe of stakeholder groups.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> procedures in determining a suitable <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor strategy might look alikein these two locati<strong>on</strong>s, but the substance of theoutcome would be sharply different. And in allcases, the process is messy and imprecise, yielding<strong>on</strong>ly what would appear to be the best fitting policiesgiven the imperfect in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> available topolicymakers at the time and the current politicalrealities.impediments to <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorimplementati<strong>on</strong>. That is the subject of Secti<strong>on</strong> 3.Without looking bey<strong>on</strong>d the generic influence <strong>on</strong>implementati<strong>on</strong> to any specific cases, we can seethat the legal empowerment movement has taken<strong>on</strong> a stiff but not infeasible implementati<strong>on</strong> challenge.We have placed much stress <strong>on</strong> the need<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> imaginative and adaptable policymaking, butto help imaginati<strong>on</strong> al<strong>on</strong>g it is imperative to havea number of rough roadmaps that will help totake policymakers around some of the pitfalls and314


3.Roadmaps toImplementati<strong>on</strong>Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to legally empower the poor are multi-faceted.Besides technical analysis and prescripti<strong>on</strong>,successful implementati<strong>on</strong> of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms calls <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>c<strong>on</strong>sensus building, participati<strong>on</strong> of key stakeholders,compromise, c<strong>on</strong>tingency planning, adaptati<strong>on</strong>,and flexibility. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are the ‘how’ or methodissues of implementati<strong>on</strong>. Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms never proceedin a straight line; change is multi-directi<strong>on</strong>al andcalls <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> acti<strong>on</strong>s — by d<strong>on</strong>ors, government, NGOs,the private sector, and communities — sometimesiteratively, sometimes simultaneously, and sometimessequentially. To guide and track the necessaryacti<strong>on</strong>s to achieve re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ends, a roadmap isuseful to identify and to incorporate the technical,instituti<strong>on</strong>al, and political and dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process.In developing an implementati<strong>on</strong> roadmap <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor, ourworking group adapted a practical template developedby Brinkerhoff and Crosby (2002), whichdraws <strong>on</strong> policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m research from multiplesectors. This template builds <strong>on</strong> empirical analysisthat identifies a comm<strong>on</strong> set of tasks associatedwith successful re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m design and implementati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se tasks follow a generalised (but notlockstep) pattern, which can be c<strong>on</strong>ceived of as aninteractive cycle comprising the following phases:policy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong> and legitimisati<strong>on</strong>, c<strong>on</strong>stituencybuilding, resource mobilisati<strong>on</strong>, implementati<strong>on</strong>design and organisati<strong>on</strong>al development, and acti<strong>on</strong>planning and progress m<strong>on</strong>itoring. A stream of issues,agendas and decisi<strong>on</strong>s launch the cycle and,over time, provide additi<strong>on</strong>al input and momentumto the process.Figure 5.4, adapted from Brinkerhoff and Crosby(2002), illustrates this iterative process of policyimplementati<strong>on</strong>, showing junctures or ‘crossroads’Figure 5.4Roadmap to the Implementati<strong>on</strong> CycleActi<strong>on</strong> Planning& ProgressM<strong>on</strong>itoringImplementati<strong>on</strong>Design &Organizati<strong>on</strong>alDeelopmentIssuesAgendasDecisi<strong>on</strong>sPolicy Formulati<strong>on</strong>andLegitimizati<strong>on</strong>C<strong>on</strong>stituencyBuildingResourceMobilizati<strong>on</strong>primary linkagesec<strong>on</strong>darywhere choices must be made while moving thepolicy <strong>on</strong>ward. Below is a brief descripti<strong>on</strong> of tasksassociated with each decisi<strong>on</strong> point <strong>on</strong> the roadmap.Issues, Agendas, and Decisi<strong>on</strong>s: Advocating <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>change, developing policy issues, lists of items tobe c<strong>on</strong>sidered, and making decisi<strong>on</strong>s that launch<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms are theprecursors to crafting the operati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>tent of aspecific policy. For these activities, it is politiciansand interest groups that tend to take the lead butthey will seldom succeed without pressure frombelow and mobilisati<strong>on</strong> and demands from thepoor themselves. Out of this process, in the ideal,a policy champi<strong>on</strong> will emerge (this could be aninfluential individual, a change team, or a coaliti<strong>on</strong>315


of interests). Without the commitment to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mand the political will to empower the poor, it isdifficult, if not impossible, to move to implementati<strong>on</strong>.Commitment and political will depend up<strong>on</strong>incentives; thus <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms must identify and create reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> governmentand other entrenched interests to back (orat least not vigorously oppose) the pro-poor policy.Policy Formulati<strong>on</strong> and Legitimisati<strong>on</strong>: Address thetechnical c<strong>on</strong>tent of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m measures. However, besidestechnical c<strong>on</strong>tent, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m measures need tobe accepted and seen as necessary and important.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor should, through their representatives, bepart and parcel of the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m design process.C<strong>on</strong>stituency Building: C<strong>on</strong>vince beneficiaries ofthe advantages of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, and dem<strong>on</strong>strate thatl<strong>on</strong>g-term benefits are worth short-term costs.Resource Mobilisati<strong>on</strong>: Ensure flow of adequateresources by addressing incentives, and exercisingleadership in galvanizing c<strong>on</strong>stituencies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>recommendati<strong>on</strong>s of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> call up<strong>on</strong>countries to undertake re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that will requirefinancial, technical, and human resource commitments.Implementati<strong>on</strong> Design and Organisati<strong>on</strong>al Development:Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers need to create and nurturenetworks and partnerships <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> cooperati<strong>on</strong> and coordinati<strong>on</strong>,and provide <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the development of neworganisati<strong>on</strong>al skills and capacities in the public,private and n<strong>on</strong>-governmental sectors. Old procedures,operating routines, and communicati<strong>on</strong>patterns die hard; change is likely to be resistedwithin some quarters.Acti<strong>on</strong> Planning and Progress M<strong>on</strong>itoring: Set upsystems and procedures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> obtaining feedbackso that implementati<strong>on</strong> is related to learning andadaptati<strong>on</strong>, so as to produce results and impact.Table 5.5 suggests the questi<strong>on</strong>s to c<strong>on</strong>sider indrawing up a roadmap <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementing <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor in a specific country— recognising that it is never possible to a havea complete understanding of the social structure,political framework and legal system be<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ehand,and that even if such <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eknowledge were possible,it would so<strong>on</strong> be outdated because the factorsthemselves are c<strong>on</strong>stantly changing.Mapping the Empowerment Domains<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor may be perceivedas a spectrum that provides opportunities, protecti<strong>on</strong>and security. It establishes a minimum ‘floor’of entitlements and safeguards to which every<strong>on</strong>eis entitled, by the simple fact of our comm<strong>on</strong>humanity. Under each of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’s fourcore themes (access to justice, security of assets,labour protecti<strong>on</strong>, and entrepreneurial rights), thetask is to establish this floor using human rightslaw. For every empowerment domain, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,<strong>on</strong>e challenge is to identify a range of potentialpolicy opti<strong>on</strong>s from which nati<strong>on</strong>s and citizens canchoose, depending <strong>on</strong> their nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text andthe different starting points of various groups ofthe poor within them. Finally, and perhaps mostsignificantly, a spectrum approach explicitly recognisesthe incremental manner in which poor peopleimprove their lives in practice. At each stage of thisimprovement, fundamental rights and an appropriatecombinati<strong>on</strong> of protecti<strong>on</strong> measures/securityand opportunities must be available to them.It would be futile to propose implementati<strong>on</strong> recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> universal applicati<strong>on</strong>; but it ispossible to put <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward stylised recommendati<strong>on</strong>sin the four domains of empowerment. Table 5.6shows how access to justice issues can be mappedwith protecti<strong>on</strong>/opportunity available in variouslegal instruments and with the goals of empowerment.316


Table 5.5 Country Specific Implementati<strong>on</strong> Roadmap: RepresentativeSummary ChecklistRe<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m implementati<strong>on</strong>‘crossroad’Issues, agendas anddecisi<strong>on</strong>sPolicy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong>— legitimisati<strong>on</strong>C<strong>on</strong>stituency buildingResource mobilisati<strong>on</strong>Implementati<strong>on</strong>design andorganisati<strong>on</strong>aldevelopmentActi<strong>on</strong> planning andprogress m<strong>on</strong>itoringQuesti<strong>on</strong>s to bear in mindC<strong>on</strong>textual analysis and checklist: Are the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s right <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a legal empowerment re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m to succeed?C<strong>on</strong>sultative process: Are the poor organised and represented by community groups, NGOs or memberbasedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s of workers?Have specifi c pro-poor policies been <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulated?What <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor policies are proposed/underway?What are the characteristics of the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor policies?What does the policy do?What is the desired impact of policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, what is it expected to accomplish or facilitate?Where did the impetus <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the policy come from?Who decided to pursue the policy, how, and why?What are the policy benefits and costs, and who is affected?What is the degree and complexity of the changes brought about by the new policy?What is the durati<strong>on</strong> of the policy change process?What instituti<strong>on</strong>s are involved in implementing the policy?How administratively intense or technically complex is the new policy?Have <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m champi<strong>on</strong>s been identified, and who are they?Have <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m policies been discussed in public <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ums and the press?Do key stakeholders see the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms as desirable?Do <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m champi<strong>on</strong>s have sufficient support and resources?Has a stakeholder analysis been c<strong>on</strong>ducted?Are c<strong>on</strong>stituencies at various societal levels organised and supportive of the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor agenda?Has the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor agenda been marketed to dem<strong>on</strong>strate its desirability and benefits?Are politicians and technocrats <strong>on</strong> board?Are representatives of the poor identified and engaged?Has oppositi<strong>on</strong> been addressed and overcome?Have resources been identified/obtained to pursue re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m policies?Have partnerships been <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med am<strong>on</strong>g government, civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s, community associati<strong>on</strong>s,and pro-poor advocates?Are d<strong>on</strong>ors <strong>on</strong> board with resources and technical support?Have capacity/resource gaps been identified? Steps taken to fill them?Has implementati<strong>on</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>sibility been assigned, and to which organisati<strong>on</strong>s or groups?Have implementati<strong>on</strong> measures been elaborated and sequenced?Have pilot sites been identified?Do implementing organisati<strong>on</strong>s/groups have the appropriate capacities, missi<strong>on</strong>s, mandates, andresources to carry out implementati<strong>on</strong> activities? If no, what modificati<strong>on</strong>s are required?Are new organisati<strong>on</strong>s/partnerships/networks required?Has the design of appropriate incentives been c<strong>on</strong>sidered and addressed?Have specifi c plans, per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance expectati<strong>on</strong>s, timetables and outcomes been developed?Do these plans include provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> early success and disseminati<strong>on</strong> of success stories?Have resistance, oppositi<strong>on</strong>, and c<strong>on</strong>flict been planned <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>?Are milest<strong>on</strong>es in place to track progress and flag the need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> adaptati<strong>on</strong>?Are mechanisms established to capture less<strong>on</strong>s learned?


Table 5.6 Empowerment Domain 1: Access to JusticeFramework of Opportunities and Protecti<strong>on</strong>s<strong>Legal</strong> Instruments Problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor People Opportunities/Protecti<strong>on</strong>s• Universal Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> HumanRights (UDHR), ICCPR, CESCR• Rights related to access toin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>; legal services;protecti<strong>on</strong>• Professi<strong>on</strong>al rules of c<strong>on</strong>duct• Extracts from other inter-nati<strong>on</strong>alhuman rights treaties (includingfundamental ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s andthe C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> indigenous andtribal peoples) c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s, UNGAresoluti<strong>on</strong>s, etc.• Lack of legal identity: indigenous,stateless, displaced• Ignorance of legal rights• Lack of access to legal services• Unjust & unaccountable legalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s• Denial of fundamental rights• Registrati<strong>on</strong> drives; right tolegal identity• Increase knowledge of rights• Improve access to legalservices• Instituti<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m/legalre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m• Capacity-building ofrepresentative organisati<strong>on</strong>sIn the sec<strong>on</strong>d empowerment domain of assetholdingrights, the major issues <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poorinclude insecurity of tenure, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced evicti<strong>on</strong>s,the appropriati<strong>on</strong> of the rural comm<strong>on</strong>s by thestate, c<strong>on</strong>fusing instituti<strong>on</strong>al, legal and regulatoryframeworks, lack of access to infrastructure, basicservices and credit, and difficulty of establishingrights. Table 5.7 shows how these might bemapped.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first task would be to identify the minimumstandard to which all human beings are entitled bytheir very humanity — in other words, the minimumfloor of protecti<strong>on</strong>. In the case of property rights, itwould be the ‘freedom from evicti<strong>on</strong>’. No <strong>on</strong>e shouldfeel threatened with being removed from their placeof residence without due process and compensati<strong>on</strong>,including the possibility of resettlement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mainsources of this protecti<strong>on</strong> include the Universal Declarati<strong>on</strong>of Human Rights (UDHR), the Internati<strong>on</strong>alCovenant <strong>on</strong> Civil and Political Relati<strong>on</strong>s (ICCPR)and the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Social Covenant(ICESR); <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenous peoples, the Indigenousand Tribal Peoples C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>, 1989 (ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>No. 169). In additi<strong>on</strong>, there is an internati<strong>on</strong>allyrecognised ‘Right to Adequate Housing’, whichincludes security of tenure as <strong>on</strong>e of its six comp<strong>on</strong>ents.New opportunities and protecti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor couldinclude systemic re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms to legal, regulatory andinstituti<strong>on</strong>al frameworks to simplify procedures andsystems, the recogniti<strong>on</strong> and training of para-professi<strong>on</strong>als(valuators, surveyors, etc.), extending housingmicro-finance ‘down-market’ to reach the poor, community-basedsavings linked to urban poor funds,low cost and decentralised surveying and registries ofland, recogniti<strong>on</strong> and registrati<strong>on</strong> of customary andcomm<strong>on</strong> property rights in the name of rural poorand indigenous people, and freehold titles where appropriateand af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> spectrum of land rights (see Box 5.5) hassome important policy implicati<strong>on</strong>s that couldin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m a practical approach to the follow-up workof the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>, namely implementing a legalempowerment agenda in the area of land rights. Agovernment could initially make a public statementor decree that residents of unauthorised settlementswill not be evicted without due process. This318


Table 5.7 Empowerment Domain 2: Property RightsFramework of Opportunities and Protecti<strong>on</strong>s<strong>Legal</strong> Instruments Problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor People Opportunities/Protecti<strong>on</strong>s• Universal Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>Human Rights (UDHR), ICCPR,CESCR• Habitat Agenda• Right to adequate housing,including security of tenure,General Comment 4 & 7• Pinheiro Principles <strong>on</strong>Restituti<strong>on</strong> of Housing, Landand Property Rights• Extract from other internati<strong>on</strong>alhuman rights treaties,c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s, declarati<strong>on</strong>s, etc(in particular Indigenous andTribal Peoples C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>,1969 (ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> No. 169)• Insecurity of tenure• Forced evicti<strong>on</strong>s• Comm<strong>on</strong>-property appropriatedby the state• N<strong>on</strong>-respect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> rights ofindigenous and tribal peoples• <strong>Legal</strong> and instituti<strong>on</strong>al barriers(path to property, overlappingmandates, professi<strong>on</strong>alreluctance)• Lack of access to infrastructureand basic services• Lack of access to credit• Spectrum approach to security oftenure• Guidelines to promote due process inthe event of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced evicti<strong>on</strong>s• Pro-poor land and agrarian re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms• Joint titling and re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ofdiscriminatory inheritance laws andpractices regarding land• Skills development of paraprofessi<strong>on</strong>als(e.g., ‘barefootsurveyors’)• Extending housing micro-finance‘down-market’• Community-based savings linked tourban poor fundswould enable residents to invest in improvementsto their home and community that would havebeneficial side effects <strong>on</strong> other aspects of their life,particularly health. As resources permit, securitycould be increased, facilitating further investments.This incremental process would help ensurethat the tenure increases take place at the pace ofthe urban poor and do not unintenti<strong>on</strong>ally result in‘downward raiding’ by the middle-class — possiblyresulting in market-based evicti<strong>on</strong>s of the poor.On the labour rights fr<strong>on</strong>t, the major c<strong>on</strong>cern ishow to ensure decent work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor facen<strong>on</strong>-respect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> fundamental principles and rightsat work, a lack of legal recogniti<strong>on</strong> of workers andtheir organisati<strong>on</strong>s in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy (andto some extent in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy), instituti<strong>on</strong>aland regulatory issues, unsafe working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s,the specific problems of vulnerable groups such aschildren, and the lack of social security and protecti<strong>on</strong>.As in the case of land, workers find themselvesin a range of situati<strong>on</strong>s, from those in which theyare denied all opportunities (being subjected to<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour) to those in which they enjoy opportunities<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> full and productive employment, accompaniedby basic security. Unlike land the spectrum<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal empowerment in relati<strong>on</strong> to rights at workshould focus <strong>on</strong> the extent of opportunity/protecti<strong>on</strong>enjoyed by a particular worker or group of workers.This is to avoid <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal legal classificati<strong>on</strong>s (‘casualwork’, ‘independent c<strong>on</strong>tractor’, etc.) which varyacross legal systems. Fundamental principles andrights at work are particularly vital in the market <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>unskilled labour that is the main source of income<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor.In relati<strong>on</strong> to labour issues, protecti<strong>on</strong>/security andopportunities could be mapped al<strong>on</strong>g an ‘upwardsarrow’ spectrum towards decent work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all (fulland freely chosen productive employment, carriedout in c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of dignity, equity and security).Fundamental principles governing work (e.g.,freedom of associati<strong>on</strong>, freedom from <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour,child labour and discriminati<strong>on</strong>) involve both319


Box 5.6 Gold Rush in M<strong>on</strong>golia: from Herders to ‘Ninjas’Harsh winters in M<strong>on</strong>golia have been <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cing traditi<strong>on</strong>alherder families to eke out a living as in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal miners.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers laid off from <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal mining sites were the firstto mine in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mally. From the green plastic c<strong>on</strong>tainersthey wear <strong>on</strong> their backs in turtle style, they are knownas ‘ninjas’. An estimated 100,000 men, women andchildren engage in in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal mining (the entire populati<strong>on</strong>is <strong>on</strong>ly 2.7 milli<strong>on</strong>), producing the same level as <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malmining companies. Exposure to mercury used to extractgold from the ore puts the miners, especially the children,at serious risk.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> M<strong>on</strong>golian Employers Federati<strong>on</strong> (MONEF) has beenseeking a new law to govern in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal mining. At the sametime, it has been raising awareness am<strong>on</strong>g the miningcompanies and providing chances <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> children of miningfamilies to receive educati<strong>on</strong> and training. Tripartitenegotiati<strong>on</strong>s (involving government, and employers’ andworkers’ representatives) agreed <strong>on</strong> changes to labour legislati<strong>on</strong>that would extend its reach to those in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy and improve protecti<strong>on</strong> against the worst <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msof child labour. So far, however, these initiatives have notbeen enacted into law.Such measures would help to fill a legislative gap thatemerged at the time of privatisati<strong>on</strong> of mining in the1990s. Legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> mining minerals and the peoplewho mine them provides an opportunity <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> coherencebetween policies <strong>on</strong> natural resource use, investment,property ownership, job creati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> adults and labourprotecti<strong>on</strong>.Source: Damdinjav Narmandakh, ‘Extending labour protecti<strong>on</strong> to thein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy in M<strong>on</strong>golia,’ in David Tajgman, ed., ExtendingLabour <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> to All <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers: Promoting Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy in Cambodia, Thailand and M<strong>on</strong>golia (ILO, Bangkok, 2006),pp 105-153; ‘Gold rush in M<strong>on</strong>golia: When shepherds become‘ninjas’.’ ILO: About the ILO, 2 Sept. 2005.opportunities and protecti<strong>on</strong>s. For example, thelegal protecti<strong>on</strong> prohibiting children from engagingin the worst <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of child labour (that can stunttheir growth and c<strong>on</strong>demn them to a life of povertyas unskilled workers) needs to be accompanied byopportunities to attend school and acquire marketableskills.Similarly, the exercise of freedom of associati<strong>on</strong>goes hand in hand with legal protecti<strong>on</strong>s thatpermit easy registrati<strong>on</strong> of trade uni<strong>on</strong>s, smallemployers, cooperatives and small traders’ associati<strong>on</strong>s,whether they are in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal or in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> security/protecti<strong>on</strong> dimensi<strong>on</strong> hasobvious relevance in relati<strong>on</strong> to protecting workers’health and ensuring a social floor that keeps themfrom falling back into poverty when a family healthemergency strikes. For example, the Zambian C<strong>on</strong>gressof Trade Uni<strong>on</strong>s and the Alliance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ZambiaIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Associati<strong>on</strong>s launched a partnershipin 2002. (Another illustrati<strong>on</strong> from M<strong>on</strong>goliais presented in Box 5.6.) Moreover, the ability toachieve decent work <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> all will be c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ed bythe job-creating or job-destroying effects of internati<strong>on</strong>aland nati<strong>on</strong>al macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policies, sothis dimensi<strong>on</strong> would need to be captured as wellTable 5.8 shows how labour rights can be mappedwith the protecti<strong>on</strong> and security available in variouslegal and other instruments and with the opportunitiesand protecti<strong>on</strong>s implicit in the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor agenda.Establishing entrepreneurial rights also impliesa broad policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m agenda (Table 5.9). Withinthe mandate of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>, the major issues<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor business people include lack of recogniti<strong>on</strong>and vulnerability, lack of credit and capital,absence of social security, lack of protecti<strong>on</strong> oflabour and of assets, and instituti<strong>on</strong>al barriers tothe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy such as complicated procedures(entry/exit, expansi<strong>on</strong> of business c<strong>on</strong>tracts,c<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong>). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re would be a possiblespectrum from the street hawker or fisher without320


Table 5.8 Empowerment Domain 3: Labour RightsFramework of Opportunities and Protecti<strong>on</strong>s<strong>Legal</strong> and Other Instruments Problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor People Opportunities/Protecti<strong>on</strong>s• Universal Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>Human Rights (UDHR), CESPR,CCPR• ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s• Extracts from otherinternati<strong>on</strong>al human rightstreaties, declarati<strong>on</strong>s, etc.• Rights to decent work/livelihoods• Nati<strong>on</strong>al labour laws• Collective bargainingagreements• Some corporate codes ofc<strong>on</strong>duct• Earnings inadequate to supportfamily• Lack of recogniti<strong>on</strong>• Denial of freedom ofassociati<strong>on</strong>• Instituti<strong>on</strong>al barriers/issues• Unsafe working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s• Child labour• Forced/b<strong>on</strong>ded labour• Discriminati<strong>on</strong>• Barriers to combining work andfamily• Lack of social security/protecti<strong>on</strong>• Low productivity and l<strong>on</strong>g hours• Productive employment with higherincomes• Skill acquisiti<strong>on</strong>/upgrading• Balanced regulati<strong>on</strong> of subc<strong>on</strong>tracting• Improved en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement mechanismsand other instituti<strong>on</strong>s• <strong>Legal</strong> framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> str<strong>on</strong>ger collectiverepresentati<strong>on</strong>• Minimum package of labour rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy workers• Innovati<strong>on</strong>s in social protecti<strong>on</strong>• Measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> gender and indigenousequity• Rapid, efficient and low-cost disputeresoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanismsassets, to the petty trader, the mobile hairdresser,the shopkeeper or tea-shop owner to the smallbusiness pers<strong>on</strong> with less than five employees,and the larger <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal sector business. All thesedifferent entrepreneurs require different levels ofprotecti<strong>on</strong> and access to different kinds of opportunities.Examples of these rules and instituti<strong>on</strong>s areguarantees of fundamental rights, member-basedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, cooperatives, access to financialservices, social security innovati<strong>on</strong>s, insurance,credit, equity and capital.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se questi<strong>on</strong>s become even more important becausethe <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’s intent is not to push legalTable 5.9 Empowerment Domain 4: Business RightsFramework of Opportunities and Protecti<strong>on</strong>s<strong>Legal</strong> Instruments Problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poor People Opportunities/Protecti<strong>on</strong>s• Universal Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>Human Rights (UDHR)• Rights to livelihoods• Right to development• Extract from other internati<strong>on</strong>alhuman rights treaties,c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s, declarati<strong>on</strong>s, etc.• Lack of recogniti<strong>on</strong>-vulnerability• Instituti<strong>on</strong>al barriers to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy: Complicated procedures(entry/exit, expansi<strong>on</strong> of businessc<strong>on</strong>tracts, c<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong>)• Health and envir<strong>on</strong>mental risks• Lack of credit and capital• Lack of social security/protecti<strong>on</strong>• Registrati<strong>on</strong>• Member-based organisati<strong>on</strong>s(associati<strong>on</strong>s, cooperatives)• Access to credit, equity andcapitalisati<strong>on</strong>• Rapid, efficient and low-costdispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms• Social security deficits (insurance)321


e<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, per se, but legal empowerment of thepoor. Policy changes must provide poor people withan instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment that offers protecti<strong>on</strong>,and in additi<strong>on</strong>, provides incentives so that theycan develop their full capabilities as individuals.This becomes a difficult agenda to implement becausein too many developing countries, rights thatare well articulated in legislati<strong>on</strong> are simply notrespected; in other developing countries, there iswell-functi<strong>on</strong>ing statutory legal regime, but it oftenmainly serves the interests of the middle and upperincome brackets. In some cases, the same law canbe used against the poor.We should also make menti<strong>on</strong> of the legalregimes based <strong>on</strong> customary and sometimesreligious rules and social compacts. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are welldescribed and increasingly rely <strong>on</strong> some <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m ofdocumentati<strong>on</strong> nested in local instituti<strong>on</strong>s, but notrecognised by statutory law. It is the poor, as previouslydiscussed, who typically use these regimes.Formal instituti<strong>on</strong>s and regulati<strong>on</strong>s are too complex,with technical standards set too high. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>lack of legal identity cuts off access to basic opportunities,such as educati<strong>on</strong>. At the same time,lack of identity exposes the poor to harassment andviolence. Ignorance and illiteracy prevent accessingopportunities and ensuring en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement oflegal obligati<strong>on</strong>s. Special opportunity-measures areoften required <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> women and the more vulnerablegroups, including children and indigenous peoples.to local realities. This secti<strong>on</strong> presents a framework<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> discussing the potential activities that couldbe undertaken at the global, regi<strong>on</strong>al nati<strong>on</strong>al andlocal levels to support the implementati<strong>on</strong> of the<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor agenda.Table 5.10 presents an indicative summary ofpotential strategies and activities to be c<strong>on</strong>sideredin the implementati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor agenda at the global, regi<strong>on</strong>al nati<strong>on</strong>aland local levels.Activities at global levelActivities at global level would likely focus <strong>on</strong> twotypes of activities to support <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor at the country level: advocacy andknowledge management. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mer would focus<strong>on</strong> getting key messages out to important targetaudiences through a variety of vehicles. For theWorld Bank’s World Development Report, a periodof six m<strong>on</strong>ths is usually allocated to promoting thekey messages after the launch date. A website, or a‘brand/logo’ that can be added to existing websites,would become the future repository of the followupto the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>, providing updates and progressreports <strong>on</strong> how the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor agenda is being implemented. An inventoryof evidence <strong>on</strong> capacity development in domainssimilar to <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor wouldbe compiled, and dialogue would be supported todisseminate global good practices.Mapping the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor Agenda at Different Political/Administrative Levels<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is also a need <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘global public goods’ or activitiesundertaken at the global level that will havean important role to play in supporting countrylevelactivities. Moreover, as the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> itselfhas stated, important differences exist betweencountries and even between regi<strong>on</strong>s that also call<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a flexible, demand-driven approach appropriate322Knowledge management activities would build <strong>on</strong>initial inventories of good practice, <strong>on</strong>-going initiativesand actors engaged in promoting empowermentcollected through the process of preparing the<str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’s report. A key element would be toidentify existing indicators and m<strong>on</strong>itoring ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts tofurther the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor agenda.Similarly, and particularly in the case of the rightsto justice and asset holding, evaluati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> learningwill be vital.


Table 5.10 LEP Implementati<strong>on</strong> Strategies and Indicative ActivitiesPolitical/Admin.LevelWorldAdvocacy• High Level Meetingwithin the frameworkof the UN• Identify globalprinciples of <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment ofthe Poor and promoteas vehicle <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>poverty reducti<strong>on</strong>• Media strategy andcampaign promoting<strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Pooragenda• Mobilise d<strong>on</strong>ors• Target setting inrelati<strong>on</strong> to 2015• Periodic reports <strong>on</strong>state of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof thePoor• WebsiteKnowledgeManagement• Inventory of existinginitiatives andactors• Inventory existingevaluati<strong>on</strong>s andanalyse less<strong>on</strong>s• Develop analyticalframeworks <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>evaluati<strong>on</strong> (includingfrom gender/indigenousperspectives)• Developing indicatorsand <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof thePoor m<strong>on</strong>itoring• Strengthen statisticalbases <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>textualanalysis• Establish supportnetworks of professi<strong>on</strong>als,academics,etc.Pilot Initiatives• Develop countryselecti<strong>on</strong> criteria• C<strong>on</strong>duct globalsurvey• Engage in dialoguewith potential countriesand supportorganisati<strong>on</strong>s• Develop <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof thePoor interventi<strong>on</strong>logic and strategy(logical frameworkapproach)• Develop assessmenttools• Gender audit• Use Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong>Strategies andDecent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> CountryProgrammemesCapacity Development• Advocacy to changeorganisati<strong>on</strong>aland managementpractices to favour<strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor• Inventory of existingcapacity-buildingprogrammemes• Inventory of toolkits,tools and methodsto support implementati<strong>on</strong>• Undertake capacityneeds/gap assessmentRegi<strong>on</strong> andsub-regi<strong>on</strong>• Regi<strong>on</strong>al and subregi<strong>on</strong>aladvocacystrategies with relevantpolitical andfinancial bodies• Regi<strong>on</strong>al SocialC<strong>on</strong>tracts• Ministerial meetings• Awareness raising• Sharing of Regi<strong>on</strong>alBest Practice• Regi<strong>on</strong>al progressm<strong>on</strong>itoring• Regi<strong>on</strong>al reports• Cooperati<strong>on</strong> betweenimplementingcountries,development banks,and political andec<strong>on</strong>omic regi<strong>on</strong>alinstituti<strong>on</strong>s• Peer-exchangeswithin and betweenregi<strong>on</strong>s• Knowledge plat<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m<strong>on</strong> capacity developmentand evaluativeevidenceIn additi<strong>on</strong>, a range of activities would be undertakento prepare <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> country-level work. Countriesand internati<strong>on</strong>al support organisati<strong>on</strong>s wouldbe identified to support the process of changeat country level. Resources would be mobilised.Pro-poor toolkits and methods to support capacity-buildingwould also be inventoried and gapsidentified. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se would be made available througha variety of avenues — websites, workshops, etc.Activities at the Regi<strong>on</strong>al andSub-regi<strong>on</strong>al LevelsAt the regi<strong>on</strong>al and sub-regi<strong>on</strong>al levels, activitieswould also likely focus <strong>on</strong> advocacy and knowledgemanagement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> regi<strong>on</strong> and sub-regi<strong>on</strong> arecritical <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the success of the legal empowermentagenda; it is at these levels that global norms canbe adapted to different socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>texts.Building political will <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change will occur through323


Table 5.10 LEP Implementati<strong>on</strong> Strategies and Indicative Activities c<strong>on</strong>t.Political/Admin.LevelNati<strong>on</strong>Advocacy• Nati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof thePoor Campaigns• Integrate <strong>Legal</strong>Empowermentof the Poor intopoverty reducti<strong>on</strong>strategies/ nati<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment plans/decent work countryprogrammemesKnowledgeManagement• Establishingbaselines andm<strong>on</strong>itoring progressregarding <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment ofthe Poor• Situati<strong>on</strong> Analyses• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>matic studies• Who’s doing whatwhere in <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof thePoorPilot Initiatives• Pilot countries step<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward/ are identified• Pilot initiativesCapacity Development• Inventory of existingsupport structuresand needs• Collaborati<strong>on</strong> withprofessi<strong>on</strong>al orgsand academia totrain grassrootsprofessi<strong>on</strong>als• Set up and activate<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ums <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> stateinterface with thepoorLocality• Rights awareness• In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> campaigns• Opportunitiesawareness• Identifying grassrootsexperience• Identifying partners• Pilot initiatives inup to four thematicareas• Support to grassroots/communitybasedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s• Support to grassrootsprofessi<strong>on</strong>alsand para-professi<strong>on</strong>als• Facilitate communityengagementtechniques and<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>umsregi<strong>on</strong>al and sub-regi<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s (e.g.African Uni<strong>on</strong>, ASEAN, etc.), U.N. Regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>s(e.g. ECA, ESCAP, ECLAC), sub-regi<strong>on</strong>albodies such as SADAC, Mercosur and in partnershipwith regi<strong>on</strong>al development banks (AfricanDevelopment Bank, Asian Development Bank, Inter-AmericanDevelopment Bank). A series of new‘Regi<strong>on</strong>al Social C<strong>on</strong>tracts’ could be an importantmechanism to <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ge political c<strong>on</strong>sensus <strong>on</strong> thelegal empowerment agenda.of the Poor. For example, francoph<strong>on</strong>e countries inWest Africa are already taking steps to streamlinetheir commercial codes under the framework ofthe Organisati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of AfricanBusiness <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>. In terms of implementati<strong>on</strong>, peerexchangemechanisms can facilitate the sharing ofcountry level experience in policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.Activities at Nati<strong>on</strong>al LevelImplementati<strong>on</strong> of empowering policies ideallyExisting ministerial <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ums could be good opportunitiestakes place at the nati<strong>on</strong>al level, where the chanceto promote <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor and is greatest to have wide impact <strong>on</strong> poverty; how-existing peer-exchange mechanisms will be possibleever, the aim should probably not be to establishplat<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> aggregating regi<strong>on</strong>al demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a ‘legal empowerment programmeme’ as a standever,nati<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Forums already engaged in law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal<strong>on</strong>e entity; rather, it should be to integrate <strong>Legal</strong>am<strong>on</strong>g countries would have a natural interest Empowerment of the Poor into existing processes,in the issues being raised by <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment such as the preparati<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al development324


plans, poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> strategies (PRSs), UNDevelopment Assistance Frameworks (UNDAFs),etc. Another important dimensi<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al levelwork will involve working closely with professi<strong>on</strong>alassociati<strong>on</strong>s (lawyers, surveyors, planners, localauthorities, micro-finance instituti<strong>on</strong>s, Chambers ofCommerce, labour uni<strong>on</strong>s, farmers’ organisati<strong>on</strong>s,etc.) to create a new generati<strong>on</strong> of professi<strong>on</strong>als inthe spirit of the ‘barefoot engineers’ that have beenpi<strong>on</strong>eered in South Asia. 9Activities at the Local LevelWithout support from the base organisati<strong>on</strong>s of thepoor, there is little chance of realising the <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor agenda. Involving thesegroups in the design of interventi<strong>on</strong>s of any kind(advocacy, knowledge management, pilot initiatives,and capacity development) is crucial. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>disseminati<strong>on</strong> will be a central strategy atthe local level. In some countries with particularlyweak or oppressive nati<strong>on</strong>al governments, communityempowerment activities may be the <strong>on</strong>lyfeasible <strong>on</strong>es. Where social mobilisati<strong>on</strong> is str<strong>on</strong>g,however, the legal empowerment agenda can bebuilt, bottom-up, by supporting existing initiativesof the urban poor, such as the pi<strong>on</strong>eering urbanpoor funds in Cambodia, India and elsewhere.4. Country LevelApproaches, Toolkits andIndices<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> pathways to <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorare multi-tiered with many possible intersecti<strong>on</strong>s,roundabouts, dead-ends, detours, and shortcuts.Given the opti<strong>on</strong>s, carrying out <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor takes a variety of different country-levelapproaches, tools or specific techniques<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> manipulating the ‘how’ of policy. For countriespromoting the legal empowerment agenda, identifyingthe appropriate process, picking the righttools and establishing the appropriate benchmarks<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> success are critical.Countries Piloting <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re has been a tremendous positive resp<strong>on</strong>searound the world to the idea of pro-poor legalempowerment. As the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> moves from theglobal to the country level, a process must be developedto enable, where appropriate, the matchingof the demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m with the appropriatesupply of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, expertise and experience.Different countries will wish to take different pathsto legal empowerment. Some of the critical issuesthat countries and their development partners willhave to address are:Historical and social c<strong>on</strong>text: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> objectives oflegal empowerment aim at achieving systemicchange in the relati<strong>on</strong>s between the poor, the stateand the market. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> historic c<strong>on</strong>text will greatlyaffect the possibility to achieve change of thismagnitude and the timing should be carefully c<strong>on</strong>sidered.Is the country ready to undertake the legalempowerment challenge? Comparing data regardingec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, inequality and social exclusi<strong>on</strong>,and poverty will be important in assessing the325


need and the potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> success.Political will: As the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m agenda affects theinstituti<strong>on</strong>s and structures of government, highlevel political support must be ensured. Evidenceof government commitment will include additi<strong>on</strong> oflegal empowerment to nati<strong>on</strong>al development plans,poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> strategies and, perhaps mostimportantly, nati<strong>on</strong>al budget allocati<strong>on</strong>s.Grass-roots and civil society capacity: To sustainthe momentum <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m will require the activeand sustained support of civil society, perhapsmore than any other entity with the excepti<strong>on</strong> ofgovernment. Assessing its capacity to drive andsustain change is critical.Governance: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> quality of governance — theprocesses, rules and organisati<strong>on</strong>s supportingdevelopment — will have an important bearing<strong>on</strong> the likelihood of success in implementing <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> relati<strong>on</strong>s betweengovernment, civil society and the professi<strong>on</strong>al andprivate sectors will make or break the chances <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>success. Political risk mapping and stakeholderanalysis will be useful tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> managing politicalrisk.External support: <strong>Legal</strong> empowerment processesmust be nati<strong>on</strong>ally owned, but outsiders can playan important role in supporting the quality of there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process and in helping to deliver specificoutputs that will build the momentum <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change.Assessing d<strong>on</strong>or interest and the capacity of externalsupport organisati<strong>on</strong>s will be important.Choosing the appropriate country levelprocessA variety of opti<strong>on</strong>s exist <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> countries, and theorganisati<strong>on</strong>s that support them, to drive the legalempowerment agenda. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> opti<strong>on</strong> chosen willdepend <strong>on</strong> the specific country c<strong>on</strong>text and will beaffected by such factors as the strength of civil society,private sector and d<strong>on</strong>or interest, date of thenext electi<strong>on</strong>s, preparati<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al developmentstrategy, and other time sensitive issues affectingthe policy window. Opti<strong>on</strong>s include:• Nati<strong>on</strong>al civil society or academia collect in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>and get specific issues, such as <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor, into the policy debateand <strong>on</strong> the table.• Governments develop projects in a department/ministry as part of their <strong>on</strong> going developmentplans and programmemes, independent of d<strong>on</strong>orsupport.• Governments and d<strong>on</strong>ors agree <strong>on</strong> specific legalempowerment projects. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se can include theestablishment of project implementati<strong>on</strong> unitswhose intent is to facilitate <strong>on</strong>-the-job trainingof government officials or, more direct methods,such as establishing an implementati<strong>on</strong> cell ina senior office, possibly even the Office of thePresident. In so doing, care should be takennot to sideline other instituti<strong>on</strong>s that may needstrengthening, such as law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m commissi<strong>on</strong>s.• Building <strong>on</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m processes in any ofthe four legal empowerment domains, rangingacross broad nati<strong>on</strong>al processes such as nati<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment plans or poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> strategies.• Establishing multi-stakeholder processes thatinclude government, civil society and externalpartners. One such example is the country-leveladaptati<strong>on</strong> of the Harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong>, Alignment andCoordinati<strong>on</strong> (HAC) process emerging from the2005 Paris Declarati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Aid Effectiveness (seeBox 5.7 describing the Kenya HAC process inthe land sector). D<strong>on</strong>ors can choose from a widevariety of funding mechanisms to support thisprocess, ranging from direct budget support tothe establishment of basket funds.• Using the coordinati<strong>on</strong> and funding mechanisms326


Box 5.7 Land Sector Harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong>, Alignment andCoordinati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poverty Reducti<strong>on</strong> in KenyaIn line with the new agenda <strong>on</strong> aid effectiveness, theDevelopment Partners Group <strong>on</strong> Land (DPGL) aims todeliver and manage aid to the land sector in Kenya asto meet the principles of harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong>, alignment andcoordinati<strong>on</strong> (HAC). In its activities and cooperati<strong>on</strong>with other stakeholders, the DPGL strives to achievec<strong>on</strong>sensus and support around the policy directi<strong>on</strong> ofthe government instead of pursuing diverging agendas.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> emphasis of the group is <strong>on</strong> three areas: 1) strengtheninggovernment capacity to develop and implementland-related policies and programmemes; 2) aligningd<strong>on</strong>or support with government priorities as set out inits poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> strategy (PRS), and 3) avoidingduplicati<strong>on</strong> and overlapping in aid initiatives. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> landsector d<strong>on</strong>or group was officially <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med in July 2003 andit has up until 2006 channelled support to the Nati<strong>on</strong>alLand Policy Formulati<strong>on</strong> Process through a Basket Fundarrangement. Since its establishment, the d<strong>on</strong>or grouphas supported the government with investments worth ofUS$10 milli<strong>on</strong> in the land sector.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> support of the DPGL is now expanding bey<strong>on</strong>dpolicy development to cover the main activities run bythe Ministry of Land through the Land Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m SupportProgrammeme (LRSP). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> LRSP incorporates elementsrelating to the finalisati<strong>on</strong> of the land policy process,policy implementati<strong>on</strong>, instituti<strong>on</strong>al trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, thedevelopment of a pro-poor Land In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> ManagementSystems (LIMS), the implementati<strong>on</strong> of the recommendati<strong>on</strong>sof the Ndungu <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> illegal allocati<strong>on</strong>of public land and the development of Forced Evicti<strong>on</strong>Guidelines in Kenya.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se and other activities have collectively supportedthe Government’s ec<strong>on</strong>omic recovery strategy (i.e.,PRSP) as well as the government’s ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to realisethe Millennium Development Goals, particularly relatingto the Eradicati<strong>on</strong> of Extreme Poverty and Hunger(MDG 1), Promoti<strong>on</strong> of Gender Equality and Empowermentof Women (MDG 3), and Ensuring Envir<strong>on</strong>mentalSustainability (MDG 7). Development Partners financiallysupporting the Basket Fund initiative have been DFID(UK), SIDA (Sweden), DCI (Irish Aid) and USAID. Otherdevelopment partners involved in the land sector inKenya include JICA, the Embassies of Finland and Italyy,the World Bank, as well as UN related agencies such asthe FAO, UNDP, and UNEP.Source: Adapted from UN-HABITAT (2007) Global Report <strong>on</strong> HumanSettlements 2007: Enhancing Urban Safety and Security,L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>, Earthscan, p. 154established in post-disaster or post-c<strong>on</strong>flict c<strong>on</strong>textsto support the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process.After deciding <strong>on</strong> the general tack to take with regardto <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor, countrieswill likely need to agree <strong>on</strong> a more detailed process<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> managing the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process. This process willoften include a series of steps as outlined below.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are not necessarily sequential and severalsteps may have to be repeated over time as thesituati<strong>on</strong> changes.• Mobilising stakeholders: Identifying key stakeholdersand agreeing <strong>on</strong> a process and a setof principles to guide the legal empowermentagenda will be a critical step to build c<strong>on</strong>fidenceam<strong>on</strong>g stakeholders. Key issues will include coordinati<strong>on</strong>mechanisms, adopti<strong>on</strong> of a protocol oragreement, and clarificati<strong>on</strong> of roles and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities,and agreement <strong>on</strong> a broad process <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m;• Situati<strong>on</strong> analysis or legal empowerment diagnostic:A detailed assessment should be madeof the relevant issues to be addressed, includingthe relevant aspects of each of the four legal empowermentdomains. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> analysis will identifypolicy, legal and instituti<strong>on</strong>al issues, as well asgaps in resources, capacity and tools.327


• Acti<strong>on</strong> planning: Development of the goal,objectives, strategies, and specific interventi<strong>on</strong>sthat will c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the legal empowermentobjective. Critical issues will include sequencingand timing, resource c<strong>on</strong>straints, establishing am<strong>on</strong>itoring and evaluati<strong>on</strong> framework and ensuringa balance between process and products tomaintain momentum.• Pilot activities: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se should be built aroundthe idea of ‘quick wins’ — outputs — in areaswhere these are feasible. In this way <strong>on</strong>e canbuild the credibility of the legal empowermentagenda and dem<strong>on</strong>strate some initial success.Pilot activities could include a mix of practicalre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms in each of the domains, policy analysis(e.g., ‘path to property’ analysis), advocacy andawareness, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> collecti<strong>on</strong> and strengtheningcoordinati<strong>on</strong> mechanisms.• Scaling-up: Expanding the range of activities andtaking <strong>on</strong> more complicated challenges. Raisingawareness of past successes, additi<strong>on</strong>al sensitisati<strong>on</strong>,strengthening the c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> processwill all support this stage. Evaluati<strong>on</strong>s may beuseful tools here.• Instituti<strong>on</strong>alising change and the change process:Tackling some of the fundamental re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msby building <strong>on</strong> the experiences in the pilot phaseand scaling-up phase to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m the organisati<strong>on</strong>sand rules that shape the instituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text.Tools to support legal empowermentre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msAfter deciding <strong>on</strong> the general approach to be takenwith <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mersneed to c<strong>on</strong>sider numerous applied techniques,developed by anti-poverty workers, communityorganisers and re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m advocates around the world<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> carrying out activities analogous to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>’sempowerment agenda. Table 5.11 summarisessome of the pertinent pro-poor policy tools,sorting them out according to the implementati<strong>on</strong>phases where they are most, but not exclusively,applicable. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se implementati<strong>on</strong> techniques aregeneral, flexible and easy to modify; developmentpractiti<strong>on</strong>ers will need to screen out those toolsthat do not apply to their situati<strong>on</strong>, and selectthose that are workable in the particular countryc<strong>on</strong>text and suitable <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the particular task at hand.Explanati<strong>on</strong> of the toolsThree tools (stakeholder analysis, c<strong>on</strong>textualanalysis, and policy characteristics analysis)have already been covered at some length in Secti<strong>on</strong>2. All the tools are annotated in alphabeticalorder in Annex 1 (and the tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> acti<strong>on</strong> planningand m<strong>on</strong>itoring are explained further in Secti<strong>on</strong> 5).Readers are also referred to the numerous toolkitsdeveloped by internati<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s and NGOs<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> organising communities and implementingnumerous aspects of social and ec<strong>on</strong>omic developmentpolicy (see the footnote below and Annex 2<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a comprehensive inventory of toolkits). 10 Manyof these tools can be used individually or in combinati<strong>on</strong>in the implementati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. On this basis, a set of<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor indicators can bedeveloped, tailored to country circumstances.Ready-made Indicators of <strong>Legal</strong>EmpowermentBoth the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong> and m<strong>on</strong>itoring phases of<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor implementati<strong>on</strong>depend <strong>on</strong> indicators of democratisati<strong>on</strong>, good governance,human rights protecti<strong>on</strong>, and many othervariables related to legal empowerment. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re hasbeen a quantitative revoluti<strong>on</strong> in recent years ofinternati<strong>on</strong>ally comparable data <strong>on</strong> political andregulatory instituti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are now at least 150measures of different aspects of governance in thepublic domain. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se data series are of variable328


quality and utility in establishing rough baselines<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> governance am<strong>on</strong>g the nati<strong>on</strong>s of the world;they are not sufficiently developed to be of greatvalue in measuring changes in the political or legalstatus of a country’s poor men and women overtime. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are also highly aggregate and thus oflimited utility in ascertaining empowerment in aparticular sub-nati<strong>on</strong>al community or regi<strong>on</strong>.While not perfect, perhaps the best example ofinternati<strong>on</strong>al indexes relevant to <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor is the World Bank’s GovernanceResearch Indicator series. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are based <strong>on</strong>several hundred individual variables measuringpercepti<strong>on</strong>s of governance. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are organised intosix categories: rule of law, lack of political violence,quality of the regulatory framework, efficiency ofthe bureaucracy, c<strong>on</strong>trol of corrupti<strong>on</strong> and accountabilityof the political leaders. 11 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank’sdata have their uses but must be applied verycautiously in development work (Arndt and Oman2006). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Eurostat/UNDP (2004) users’ guide togovernance indicators describes at length the applicati<strong>on</strong>sand limitati<strong>on</strong>s of several of the leadingoff-the-rack governance data series.Pending reliable pre-existing empirical in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al or local-level legal empowerment,<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor programmemesand projects will have to develop and use their ownmetrics <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> evaluating the socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic envir<strong>on</strong>mentand gauging accomplishments, based <strong>on</strong>surveys and interviews, as discussed above. RuthAlsop and Nina Heinsohn (2006) report to theWorld Bank <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e such analytic framework thatcan be used to measure and m<strong>on</strong>itor empowermentprocesses and outcomes. Kucera et al. (2007) put<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward indicators that have been tested <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> measuringvarious aspects of decent work. (See Annex3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a list of readymade indicators.)5. M<strong>on</strong>itoring andEvaluati<strong>on</strong>Because acti<strong>on</strong> planning and progress m<strong>on</strong>itoring(the final row in Table 5.11) has not beendiscussed much in these pages, and becausethis functi<strong>on</strong> is especially important <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> outsideagencies, some of its tools are worth looking at abit more closely. Brinkerhoff and Crosby (2002)identify four comp<strong>on</strong>ents to establish an efficientparticipatory and country-driven policy m<strong>on</strong>itoringsystem:1. A management in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> system based <strong>on</strong>targeted indicators endorsed by nati<strong>on</strong>al stakeholders.2. Stakeholder m<strong>on</strong>itoring to identify the resp<strong>on</strong>sesof those that benefited or those that lost fromthe policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m measures.3. Problem-solving studies to devise tailored andpractical soluti<strong>on</strong>s to implementati<strong>on</strong> issues.4. Process and impact evaluati<strong>on</strong>s to supportlearning over time.Best practices recommend that the design of eachcomp<strong>on</strong>ent should be based <strong>on</strong> the principlesof adaptati<strong>on</strong> to user needs and availability ofresources, user participati<strong>on</strong>, parsim<strong>on</strong>y (the leastamount of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and cost required to accomplishthe task), and simplicity. To address boththe c<strong>on</strong>tent and process sides in m<strong>on</strong>itoring policyimplementati<strong>on</strong>, it is important to understand fullywhat needs to be m<strong>on</strong>itored.Less<strong>on</strong>s learned from country experiences have ledto the following practical suggesti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>itoringpolicy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m implementati<strong>on</strong>, according toBrinkerhoff and Crosby (2002):1. Define a list of steps, processes, targets andmilest<strong>on</strong>e events in the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process. Thiswill enable the breakdown of the policy processesinto a series of comp<strong>on</strong>ents to enable329


Table 5.11 Pro-poor policy implementati<strong>on</strong> tools*Implementati<strong>on</strong> phaseDeveloping policy issues,agendas, and decisi<strong>on</strong>sPolicy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulati<strong>on</strong> andlegitimisati<strong>on</strong>C<strong>on</strong>stituency buildingResource mobilisati<strong>on</strong>Implementati<strong>on</strong> design andorganisati<strong>on</strong>al developmentActi<strong>on</strong> planning andprogress m<strong>on</strong>itoringPossible toolsCompetencies AssessmentC<strong>on</strong>textual analysis<strong>Legal</strong> and instituti<strong>on</strong>al frameworkOpportunity RankingPolicy characteristics analysisPolitical will and risk analysisProblem CensusProblem treeSocial Baseline StudySocial Impact and Opportunities AssessmentCommunity MappingFocus groupsForce field analysisInfluence mappingInstituti<strong>on</strong>al AnalysisParticipatory Poverty AssessmentsPolicy briefingsPolitical mappingStakeholder analysisStrategic Planning Framework/SWOT/PESTC<strong>on</strong>flict preventi<strong>on</strong> and resoluti<strong>on</strong>Nati<strong>on</strong>al symposiumOutreach (Media Campaigns, School Programmemes, Public SpeakingEngagements, Publicati<strong>on</strong>s, Public Hearings, Study Circles)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>shopsAdvocacy/lobbyingDomestic resource mobilisati<strong>on</strong>FundraisingParticipatory budgetingBest practices (collecti<strong>on</strong>, disseminati<strong>on</strong>)ExchangesInstituti<strong>on</strong>al twinningInternship programmemesPara-professi<strong>on</strong>alsPlain language (translati<strong>on</strong> and disseminati<strong>on</strong> of laws)Technical assistanceTraining (<strong>on</strong> leadership, group work and related management issues)Travel grants/internships <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> officialsWeb-based supportGender auditImpact evaluati<strong>on</strong>Logical framework approachMISProblem solving studiesStakeholder m<strong>on</strong>itoring (household surveys, key in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mant interviews)* Guide to the techniques that might be appropriate during the implementati<strong>on</strong> cycle; a technique may be useful in more than <strong>on</strong>e phase of implementati<strong>on</strong>.Highlighted tools are described in Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 of this chapter.


Table 5.12 A Framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Demand-Led Assessment of Implementati<strong>on</strong>Access toJusticeE.g., To whatextent does thelaw recognizethe right of apoor pers<strong>on</strong> tobe registeredat birth?E.g., In theinstant case,how af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dablewas theregistrati<strong>on</strong>process to thepoor pers<strong>on</strong>s?Asset holdingRightsE.g., To whatextent doesthe law protectpoor tenantsfrom evicti<strong>on</strong>?Labour RightsEntrepreneurialRightsE.g., To whatextent does thelaw mandate thereducti<strong>on</strong> of costof registering abusiness bel<strong>on</strong>gingto a poor pers<strong>on</strong>?E.g., in the instantcase to what extenthas the relevantgovernment agencydecentralisedits businessregistrati<strong>on</strong> processto give access tothe poor?CapacityDevelopmentE.g., To whatextent does thelaw mandategovernmentinstituti<strong>on</strong> tosimplify procedures<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor?E.g., To whatextent does thegovernmentprovide training toits staff <strong>on</strong> legalempowerment ofthe poor?E.g., To whatextent does thegovernmentprovide accessibleguidance to thepoor <strong>on</strong> servicesavailable to themfrom governmentagencies?<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>E.g., To whatextent doesthe lawextend labourstandards tothe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omy?E.g., to whatextent doesthe relevantgovernmentagency m<strong>on</strong>itorcompliancewith labourlaws in the<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal andin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omyGovernmentimplementati<strong>on</strong>ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tsE.g., In theinstant caseto whatextent has thegovernmentdocumentedtenure rights ofthe poor?EffectivenessE.g., In theinstant case,to what extentwas the poorpers<strong>on</strong> ableto affect theregistrati<strong>on</strong>?E.g., In theinstant case,to what extentwas the poorpers<strong>on</strong> ableto retainpossessi<strong>on</strong> ofthe property?E.g., to whatextent was thepoor pers<strong>on</strong>working inthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal orthe in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malec<strong>on</strong>omyable to enjoythe benefitsof labourprotecti<strong>on</strong>laws?E.g., To what extentwas the poor pers<strong>on</strong>in the instant caseable to affect theregistrati<strong>on</strong> of his/her business?E.g., To what extentwas the poor pers<strong>on</strong>in the instant caseaware of their legalrights?an easier grasp of what needs to be m<strong>on</strong>itored.2. Make the use of qualitative rather than quantitativeapproaches in m<strong>on</strong>itoring the system, asthey offer a more complete and nuanced set ofdata that are numeric and narrative.3. Engage implementing parties and beneficiariesin the draw up of the m<strong>on</strong>itoring systems andmethodologies and acquire feedback. Thiswill simplify the process of tracking previouslyidentified indicators. Focus group discussi<strong>on</strong>s,workshops and other similar methods can beused to ensure participati<strong>on</strong>.331


4. Customize the choice of m<strong>on</strong>itoring methods tothe needs and c<strong>on</strong>straints of the implementingagencies.5. Delegate the m<strong>on</strong>itoring process to an externalbody selected from civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s,think tanks and advocacy groups, to ensuregreater independence, transparency and accountability.A possible framework <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a demand-led assessmentof government implementati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor recommendati<strong>on</strong>s is shownin Table 5.12, which is based <strong>on</strong> the framework ofthe World Resources Institute’s Access InitiativeAssessment method. Each cell of the matrix hasbeen populated with an indicator to serve as anexample. Those undertaking the assessment canrank each metric based <strong>on</strong> research guidelines anddata collected. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se assessments, when repeatedover time, will show whether and how well <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor recommendati<strong>on</strong>s arebeing implemented. 12M<strong>on</strong>itoring of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms will involve seeking answersto critical questi<strong>on</strong>s. Am<strong>on</strong>g the questi<strong>on</strong>s thatmay need to be posed are the following: Are thepolicy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms really being implemented? And if so,do they really matter? If they do make a difference,how important is it? What are the gender impacts?Taking into c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> the multiple dimensi<strong>on</strong>sof policy re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms, the pace of implementati<strong>on</strong> willlikely be gradual. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re may not even be c<strong>on</strong>spicuousimpact in the short-term. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, inthe m<strong>on</strong>itoring of progress, it will be important toestablish process indicators, and to pursue m<strong>on</strong>itoringactivities either <strong>on</strong> a c<strong>on</strong>tinuous or repetitivebasis. Furthermore, the entire set of measuringactivities — data collecti<strong>on</strong>, analysis, and interpretati<strong>on</strong>— will need to be based <strong>on</strong> the country’snati<strong>on</strong>al priorities.6. Strategy and TacticsWe have reviewed the social, political and technicalfactors that stand in the way of poor people’slegal empowerment, and set <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>th broad ideasabout how to counter those <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ces. Change agentsmust put aside prec<strong>on</strong>ceived or uni<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m approachesto <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor to thinkcreatively about how to make <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor available, af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable and acceptablein their own specific c<strong>on</strong>text. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y must be <strong>on</strong> thelook out <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> unintended c<strong>on</strong>sequences, perverseincentives, and hidden agendas. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir initiativesmust be in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>med by pilot projects that can beamended if they fail, and scaled-up and replicatedif they work.In designing empowerment policies and decidingup<strong>on</strong> how to implement them, change agents mustalways keep the following core values fr<strong>on</strong>t andcentre:• Poverty reducti<strong>on</strong> is the ultimate objective of<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor, so every re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mmust be judged by the extent to which it impartsfreedom and allows poor people to gain morec<strong>on</strong>trol over their futures and to improve theirwell-being.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> peaceful struggle against impoverishmentmust be participatory, based <strong>on</strong> respect <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> humanrights, and with poor people playing activeroles al<strong>on</strong>g the way.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> gains of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poorshould be broad-based and take into account thediversity of disadvantaged groups, in particular,the indigenous people who are often inadvertentlyoverlooked by policymakers.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> gains also must include women; there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e,another standard against which to measure <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment of the Poor policy is whether ittakes full account of gender-specific effects.332


Empowerment of the poor in the end means socialtrans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> — not <strong>on</strong>ly a more just distributi<strong>on</strong>of wealth and income, but a more expansivesharing of power so disadvantaged people canbegin bringing about significant change throughtheir own acti<strong>on</strong>s.Strategic FindingsAm<strong>on</strong>g the strategic opti<strong>on</strong>s and c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>simplied in Chapters 1 through 4 of thisvolume, a number of them stand out, and they arementi<strong>on</strong>ed below. Several are rich with paradox,and government officials, civil society members,and development practiti<strong>on</strong>ers need to sort out thec<strong>on</strong>flicting elements to determine the most promisingstrategic directi<strong>on</strong> to take <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their community,country or regi<strong>on</strong>.1.<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor is easiest toimplement where it is needed least. An effectiveadministrative state, a set of transparentand accountable political instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and agrowing ec<strong>on</strong>omy are predictors of success <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legal empowerment policies. Yet, countries thatmeet these criteria probably have their povertyand social exclusi<strong>on</strong> under relative c<strong>on</strong>trol; thebulk of the global poverty problem is in preciselythose nati<strong>on</strong>s that lack these positive attributes,so implementati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor must usually be completed under inauspiciousc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.2.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a rich base of comparative internati<strong>on</strong>alexperience, but no ready-made <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mulas <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>legal empowerment. Soluti<strong>on</strong>s that suit <strong>on</strong>e c<strong>on</strong>textmay be dead wr<strong>on</strong>g in another. Greatcare should be taken to develop interventi<strong>on</strong>sthat are appropriate <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the specific historical,socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic and political c<strong>on</strong>text of a givencountry.3.Think systemically, act incrementally. A nati<strong>on</strong>’slegal and administrative setup functi<strong>on</strong>s likean ecosystem with a heavy measure of interdependence.That implies empowerment takessystemic changes. Yet, big bang approaches arerare and they often run out of steam when theyare tried. In particular, any attempt to supplantand replace existing in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal mechanisms seemsdoomed to failure. Instead, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal mechanismsmust be gradually integrated with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal.4.Think l<strong>on</strong>g, go short. Justice, labour and landissues are complicated and do not lend themselvesreadily to a traditi<strong>on</strong>al two-year project approach.Yet, re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers can never lose sight of thefact that politicians are in office <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> finite terms.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementati<strong>on</strong> process, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, needs toinvolve actors who are less affected by electi<strong>on</strong>s,and deliver successes <strong>on</strong> a regular basis. Evenif these successes are small, they must providetangible improvements to maintain the momentum<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.5.Start from afar, but change from within. <strong>Legal</strong>empowerment is <strong>on</strong> the internati<strong>on</strong>al community’sagenda, as the very existence of this <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>proves. Yet, pro-poor policy change hasto be endogenous. Any percepti<strong>on</strong> that <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eignd<strong>on</strong>ors drive re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m may prove counter-productive.Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms that do not find champi<strong>on</strong>s andbuild c<strong>on</strong>stituencies within are likely to fail (asthey should).6. Support associati<strong>on</strong>s of the poor, but do not compromisetheir independence. Capacity-developingsupport is important to associati<strong>on</strong>s of the poor,be they small farmers’ cooperatives, communitybasedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, domestic worker trade uni<strong>on</strong>sor urban user-groups. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> inc<strong>on</strong>gruity is thatassisting these groups may cause them to becomemore accountable to the external funding agencythan to their membership.7.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> from the bottom up and the top down.D<strong>on</strong>or expectati<strong>on</strong>s regarding the interest ofthe poor in legal empowerment are often out333


of touch with the desires of the poor to get thestate to provide services and benefits throughrecourse to client c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s if necessary. Atthe same time, external change agents cannotignore the prec<strong>on</strong>cepti<strong>on</strong>s and policy positi<strong>on</strong>s ofthe internati<strong>on</strong>al agencies that are funding theirwork with <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>yneed to think about how to balance these twoperspectives.8.Decentralise…except when it is better to centralise.A comm<strong>on</strong> theme in several <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ingGroup reports is the need to decentralise resp<strong>on</strong>sibility,resources and accountability <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> legalservice delivery to the lowest level at which theycan be effectively managed. But decentralisati<strong>on</strong>also gives power to local elites opposed to the<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor agenda, so thisopti<strong>on</strong> bears watching.9.Balance demand <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change with the capacity toaccommodate change. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> energy of the poor topinpoint soluti<strong>on</strong>s to their problems, to organise,and to engage in advocacy must be met withan equally receptive state. It is important togive attenti<strong>on</strong> to official capacity to resp<strong>on</strong>d tothe thrust <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change coming upwards from thegrassroots.10. Put together in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s.In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal instituti<strong>on</strong>s and authority can be ofgreat utility in pursuing <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor, but so can official instituti<strong>on</strong>s. Policymakersneed to combine the best features ofboth to facilitate implementati<strong>on</strong>.11. Look <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> cooperati<strong>on</strong>, but anticipate c<strong>on</strong>fr<strong>on</strong>tati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor policies where all sides can benefit, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>instance land readjustment which takes irregularlysub-divided land and reallocates it<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> public and private use according to planningrequirements. However, practiti<strong>on</strong>ers als<strong>on</strong>eed to face up to the fact that compromiseand mutual adjustment are not always going tohappen with <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> narrow technical and legal aspects may bethe least c<strong>on</strong>troversial, but even those ultimatelyaffect the distributi<strong>on</strong> of power withinsociety. Governments trying to implement anempowerment agenda have to figure out wayseither to reimburse or to defuse those possiblydisadvantaged by the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Managingpolitical risk throughout the implementati<strong>on</strong>process, there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, is critical.Tactical IdeasWhile walking the tightrope of these strategicissues, change agents will also need to c<strong>on</strong>siderimplementati<strong>on</strong> tactics. A list of comm<strong>on</strong> modesof acti<strong>on</strong> is presented below. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se acti<strong>on</strong>s havebeen selected from materials put <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ward by all theworking groups involved in the preparati<strong>on</strong> of thisvolume, and are presented in no particular order.1.Be opportunistic. Take tactical advantageof opportunities as they arise and do not bec<strong>on</strong>strained by a programmemed calendar ofdeliverables.2.Use plain and local language. One of the keyelements <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al ownership is language:dialogue, debate and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> sharing mustbe c<strong>on</strong>ducted in local languages; legal documentsshould be demystified by rendering themin laypers<strong>on</strong>’s terms.3.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> with para-professi<strong>on</strong>als. A proposal raisedin several working group reports is to create anew generati<strong>on</strong> of para-professi<strong>on</strong>als, who aretrained and possibly certified to resp<strong>on</strong>d to theday-to-day service requirements of the poor, butwho do not require the advanced studies of currentprofessi<strong>on</strong>als, which are often inappropriatelyscheduled, expensive and include subjects oflimited relevance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the prospective client base.334


4.Bring existing technical soluti<strong>on</strong>s up to date.Particularly in the land sector, many of theexisting legal instruments are inadequate. Landin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> systems are often expensive, complicated,and bureaucratic and, as a result, quicklybecome outdated. Un<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>tunately, the systemsrequired, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, to integrate innovative<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms of tenure (certificates, group rights, etc.)into the nati<strong>on</strong>al spatial data infrastructure d<strong>on</strong>ot currently exist. As emphasised in Chapter 2of this report, the choice of l<strong>on</strong>g-term technicalsoluti<strong>on</strong>s must be driven by the willingness andability of the users to pay. Thus an importantelement in successful <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of thePoor implementati<strong>on</strong> will be the appropriatenessof the underlying analysis and the existence orcreati<strong>on</strong> of technical systems to support re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m.5.Bring together technical expertise and grassrootsexperience. Technocrats dominate policymakingin <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor. While validreas<strong>on</strong>s exist <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> some technical requirements,grassroots realities and community soluti<strong>on</strong>salso need to be understood and incorporated inthe re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process. If a law does not meet itsusers’ needs, it is useless to the poor.6.Dedicate resources to support participatoryprocesses and coordinati<strong>on</strong>. While technicalsoluti<strong>on</strong>s often attract significant d<strong>on</strong>or andgovernment interest, capacity development <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>participati<strong>on</strong> and coordinati<strong>on</strong> mechanisms isoften undervalued and there<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e under-funded.Other kinds of support, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, are translati<strong>on</strong>of laws and regulati<strong>on</strong>s into local languages,or grants to local civil society groups to lay bare<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor issues and tofund disseminati<strong>on</strong> campaigns. Specific supportis required <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> coordinati<strong>on</strong>, preparati<strong>on</strong> of researchand opti<strong>on</strong>s papers, and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong>.Peer exchanges (both inter-regi<strong>on</strong>aland intra-regi<strong>on</strong>al) are another valuable pro-poortool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> building commitment to re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>maintaining momentum over time.7.Provide effective outreach. Under intense pressuresto deliver, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> and communicati<strong>on</strong>programmemes are often neglected during implementati<strong>on</strong>.Yet without a dedicated outreachcampaign, clients will rarely adopt the proposedre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms. Feedback received from those involvedneeds to be cycled back into the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m process,to keep it homegrown and resp<strong>on</strong>sive to demand.8.Provide access to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>. Two-way communicati<strong>on</strong>between governments and the poorwill need to be improved. For example, access toin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> has helped people to secure tenureand to tackle job discriminati<strong>on</strong> through a betterunderstanding of their rights. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are also examplesin post-disaster and post-c<strong>on</strong>flict nati<strong>on</strong>sof the importance of providing access to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.Mobilising resources to take advantage ofin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> in support of <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment ofthe Poor presents a challenge because in manycountries in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> that is nominally ‘public’is in practice difficult to obtain. In India, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example,civil society organisati<strong>on</strong>s waged a fiercecampaign to gain access to public budget andexpenditure data using freedom of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>laws in six states, which later culminated in thepassage of a nati<strong>on</strong>al law. However, in countrieswhere civil society is weak, and where certainsocial groups have been marginalized over extendedperiods of time, the ability of the poor toengage in effective collective acti<strong>on</strong> is likely tobe limited and fragile.9.Bundle service delivery. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> strategy of bundlingservices is highlighted in several chapters of thisreport; it is seen as a cost-effective strategy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>delivering a variety of services to the poor. Anexample is to deliver identity cards with vaccinati<strong>on</strong>programmemes. Such bundling may alsohave the great potential of c<strong>on</strong>tributing to com-335


munity empowerment, especially if the deliveryis structured so as to rein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ce transparencyand accountability in community instituti<strong>on</strong>s.Experience with delivering bundled municipalservices (e.g., licensing, registrati<strong>on</strong>, tax and feepayments) through <strong>on</strong>e-stop shops offers relevantless<strong>on</strong>s of utility <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms as well. Membership-basedorganisati<strong>on</strong>s such as cooperatives, business associati<strong>on</strong>s,trade uni<strong>on</strong>s and grass-roots women’sorganisati<strong>on</strong>s can offer free or low-cost legalservices to the members.these suggesti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> strategy and tactics, remainingtrue to the core values of the legal empowermentagenda. Where their ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts prove successful,they will make it possible <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> many more peoplenow mired in poverty to improve their lot in lifewithin the <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eseeable future. While implementati<strong>on</strong>success cannot be guaranteed because of themany countervailing factors menti<strong>on</strong>ed earlier,steady, modest progress in fighting poverty withlegal tools and rights is well within the realm ofpossibility in most countries.10. Support alternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong>. All fourworking groups emphasise the need to supportalternative dispute resoluti<strong>on</strong> mechanisms,including arbitrati<strong>on</strong>, mediati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>ciliati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fundamental challenge is to avoid thecost and expense of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal litigati<strong>on</strong> in return<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decisi<strong>on</strong>s that are made transparently andcan be en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced. Less<strong>on</strong>s learned from labourcourts may be instructive in other fields aswell.11. Collaborate with professi<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s.Professi<strong>on</strong>al organisati<strong>on</strong>s are promisingpotential allies. While lawyers, nati<strong>on</strong>al barassociati<strong>on</strong>s, law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m commissi<strong>on</strong>s, andlaw schools are oriented towards meeting theneeds of the middle and upper classes, theyare also often willing to lend their professi<strong>on</strong>alexpertise to the needs of the poor. Landsurveyors, valuators, and notaries often act asgatekeepers of rules that are often divorcedfrom the realities of the urban poor or evenholdovers from the col<strong>on</strong>ial era, but they mayalso be amenable to reorienting their thinking.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> role of urban planners and local authoritiesalso merits attenti<strong>on</strong>. It may be possibleto c<strong>on</strong>vert these stakeholders from possibleopp<strong>on</strong>ents into allies <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> change.Change agents are invited to c<strong>on</strong>sider and then try336


Annex 1: PolicyImplementati<strong>on</strong> ToolsListed below are a variety of tools deemed useful<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementing policies that may help toadvance legal empowerment re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms:Advocacy/lobbying: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are attempts to influencethe outcomes of any policymaking system throughendorsements, publicity, discussi<strong>on</strong>s, etc.Best practices (collecti<strong>on</strong> and disseminati<strong>on</strong>): Abest practice is a management idea that assumesthere is a technique, method, process, activity, incentiveor reward that is more effective at deliveringa particular outcome than any other technique,method or process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> idea is that with proper processes,checks, and testing, a desired outcome canbe delivered with lessproblems and fewer un<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eseencomplicati<strong>on</strong>s.C<strong>on</strong>textual analysis: This involves a system-widereview of ec<strong>on</strong>omic, social, cultural, political, administrative,and instituti<strong>on</strong>al factors that affect theease of implementing a particular public policy in acountry, such as legal empowerment re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms.Community Mapping: A Community Map is a visualrepresentati<strong>on</strong> of what the community perceives as itscommunity space. This includes showing the boundaryof the community as understood by communitymembers and all the elements recognised by themas part of their area. Most of the spatial in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>is obtained through direct observati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> communitymembers themselves decide what does and doesnot go <strong>on</strong> the map. Some items of importance to thecommunity may not be noticeable to outsiders, suchas sacred sites or clan boundaries (ICMM, the WorldBank and ESMAP 2005).Competencies Assessment: Measuring and recordingthe skills of an individual or group is an essentialstarting point <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> any <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor implementati<strong>on</strong> strategy. Competenciesmay include knowledge, skills, and abilities as wellas other characteristics such as initiative, motivati<strong>on</strong>,legitimacy and values. Competencies can beassessed in the framework of a facilitated workshopprocess or <strong>on</strong> an individual basis, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example.C<strong>on</strong>flict resoluti<strong>on</strong>: C<strong>on</strong>flict is a normal part of relati<strong>on</strong>shipsand occurs whenever people or groupshave different expectati<strong>on</strong>s of joint or intersectingactivities. Instead of seeking to avoid c<strong>on</strong>flict atall costs, which would be unrealistic, it is better tolearn to recognise and manage c<strong>on</strong>flict as part ofgood relati<strong>on</strong>ship building and maintenance. Notall c<strong>on</strong>flicts can be resolved, but methods exist <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>managing differences between stakeholders so thatdevelopment activities can c<strong>on</strong>tinue (ICMM, theWorld Bank and ESMAP 2005).Domestic resource mobilisati<strong>on</strong>: As defined in theM<strong>on</strong>terrey C<strong>on</strong>sensus, domestic resource mobilisati<strong>on</strong>includes policies that foster good governancethat is resp<strong>on</strong>sive to the people’s needs; an appropriatepolicy and regulatory framework; the fightingof corrupti<strong>on</strong> at all levels; sound macroec<strong>on</strong>omicpolicies aimed at sustaining high growth rates, fullemployment, stability and poverty eradicati<strong>on</strong>; fiscalsustainability; investment in basic ec<strong>on</strong>omic andsocial infrastructure; improvement in working c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s;strengthening and development of the domesticfinancial sector, enhanced by microfinanceand credit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> micro- and small and medium-sizedenterprises, and the establishment of developmentbanks to further facilitate access to credit.Exchanges: Practiti<strong>on</strong>ers may visit or temporarilywork in a similar organisati<strong>on</strong> or job assignment ina <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign country to gain practical and comparativeexperience about a policy such as legal empowerment.Focus groups: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are groups selected <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their337


elevance to a particular area of investigati<strong>on</strong>, whichare engaged by a trained facilitator in discussi<strong>on</strong>sdesigned to share insights, ideas, and observati<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> the area of c<strong>on</strong>cern. Focus groups are typicallyopen-ended, discursive, and used to gain a deeperunderstanding of resp<strong>on</strong>dents’ attitudes and opini<strong>on</strong>s.A key feature is that participants are ableinteract with each other. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> group dynamic oftenprovides richer insights and data than would havebeen achieved by interviewing the participants individually(ICMM, the World Bank and ESMAP 2005)Force field analysis: Force field analysis helps clarifya group’s positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> a particular policy. It is agraphical representati<strong>on</strong> in which groups are placed<strong>on</strong> a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum from ‘oppose’ to ‘favour’, where themiddle of the c<strong>on</strong>tinuum is ‘neutral’. It is useful inproviding a quick overview of sources of major oppositi<strong>on</strong>and support (Brinkerhoff and Crosby 2002).Fundraising: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are individuals, corporati<strong>on</strong>s,foundati<strong>on</strong>s, and nati<strong>on</strong>al and internati<strong>on</strong>al governmentbodies that may be approached <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> help infunding <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.Gender audit: A participatory and self-assessmentapproach to promote organisati<strong>on</strong>al learning aboutgender mainstreaming (Moser 2005).Impact evaluati<strong>on</strong>: An impact evaluati<strong>on</strong> assesseschanges in the well-being of individuals, households,communities or firms that can be attributedto a particular project, programmeme or policy. Itis aimed at providing feedback to help improve thedesign of programmemes and policies. In additi<strong>on</strong>to providing <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> improved accountability, impactevaluati<strong>on</strong>s are useful <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> dynamic learning, allowingpolicymakers to improve <strong>on</strong>going programmemesand ultimately better allocate funds acrossprogrammemes.Influence mapping: This technique identifies theindividuals and groups with the power to effect akey decisi<strong>on</strong>. It further investigates the positi<strong>on</strong>and motives of each player and the best channelsthrough which to communicate with them (Start andHovland 2004).Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Analysis: Instituti<strong>on</strong>al analysis studiesthe instituti<strong>on</strong>al set-up in and around a givencommunity, including how important each instituti<strong>on</strong>is, how they interact with each other and whoparticipates in them. This in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> can be gatheredthrough an interview process, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, byasking community members to describe the instituti<strong>on</strong>spresent in their community, their functi<strong>on</strong>,importance in relati<strong>on</strong> to other instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and ifand how they participate in them. Instituti<strong>on</strong>al analysisis particularly useful in identifying instituti<strong>on</strong>sat the community level that can play an importantrole in the legal empowerment process (ICMM, theWorld Bank and ESMAP 2005).Instituti<strong>on</strong>al twinning: Instituti<strong>on</strong>al twinning is a<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of staff exchange. For instance, staff of a particularagency would visit a similar instituti<strong>on</strong> in a<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign country, with the aim of exchanging expertise.Often the exchange is two-way (Ouchi 2004).Internship programmemes: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are programmemesthat integrate study with planned and supervisedcareer-related work experience <strong>on</strong> practicalissues of implementati<strong>on</strong>.Logical framework approach: LFA is an analytical,presentati<strong>on</strong>al and management tool that canhelp planners and managers to analyse the existingsituati<strong>on</strong> during project preparati<strong>on</strong>, establish alogical hierarchy of means by which objectives willbe reached, identify some of the potential risks, establishhow outputs and outcomes might best bem<strong>on</strong>itored and evaluated, and present a summary ofthe project in a standard <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mat (Örtengren 2004).LFA is an overarching tool that may use other techniqueslisted here, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> instance situati<strong>on</strong>al analysisand stakeholder analysis.338


MIS: A Management In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> System is <strong>on</strong>e offour comp<strong>on</strong>ents that establish an efficient policym<strong>on</strong>itoring system (see Secti<strong>on</strong> 5). MIS is used tocollect, analyse, store, and disseminate in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>useful <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> decisi<strong>on</strong>-making in a project. It trackstargeted indicators that help in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m choices in aproject. Design of the MIS should be based <strong>on</strong> theprinciples of adaptati<strong>on</strong> to user needs, and availabilityof resources, user participati<strong>on</strong>, parsim<strong>on</strong>y,and simplicity. It is important to understand fullywhat needs to be m<strong>on</strong>itored.Nati<strong>on</strong>al symposium: This is a high-profile way topublicise <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor or otherpolicies.Opportunity Ranking: This is used to help communitymembers and development partners decideup<strong>on</strong> which projects to start implementing. Takingaccount of locally available resources, skills, andcapacities, it is built around a scoring system thatranks various opti<strong>on</strong>s against agreed criteria.Outreach: Methods <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> publicizing <strong>Legal</strong> Empowermentof the Poor or other policies include mediacampaigns, school programmemes, public speakingengagements, publicati<strong>on</strong>s, public hearings, studycircles. (Study circles, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, are a method ofadult educati<strong>on</strong> and social change popular in Scandinavia._Para-professi<strong>on</strong>als: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are people in variousoccupati<strong>on</strong>al fields, such as educati<strong>on</strong>, healthcare,and law, who have obtained a certificate by passingan exam that enables them to per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m a task requiringsignificant knowledge, but without having theoccupati<strong>on</strong>al license to per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m at the professi<strong>on</strong>allevel in the field.Participatory budgeting: Participatory budgeting isa process of democratic deliberati<strong>on</strong> and decisi<strong>on</strong>making,in which ordinary residents decide how toallocate part of a municipal or public budget. Participatorybudgeting is usually characterised by severalbasic design features: identificati<strong>on</strong> of spendingpriorities by community members, electi<strong>on</strong> ofbudget delegates to represent different communities,facilitati<strong>on</strong> and technical assistance by publicemployees, local and higher level assemblies todeliberate and vote <strong>on</strong> spending priorities, and theimplementati<strong>on</strong> of local direct-impact communityprojects. Various studies have suggested that participatorybudgeting results in more equitable publicspending, higher quality of life, increased satisfacti<strong>on</strong>of basic needs, greater government transparencyand accountability, increased levels of publicparticipati<strong>on</strong> (especially by marginalised residents),and democratic and citizenship learning.Participatory Poverty Assessments: A PPA is a toolthat allows c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> of the poor directly. Findingsare transmitted to policymakers, thereby enablingthe poor to influence policy. APPA uses a variety offlexible participatory methods that combine visualtechniques (mapping, matrices, diagrams) and verbaltechniques (open-ended interviews, discussi<strong>on</strong>groups). It also emphasises exercises that facilitatein<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> sharing, analysis, and acti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> goalis to give the intended beneficiaries more c<strong>on</strong>trolover the research process. To ensure follow-up atthe community level (a principle of participatory research),many PPAs have involved the developmentof community acti<strong>on</strong> plans subsequently supportedby local governments or NGOs (Robb, 2000).Plain language: In many countries, the law is <strong>on</strong>lydrafted and administrated in the nati<strong>on</strong>al language,which many of the poor may not speak or read.Translati<strong>on</strong> of laws into local language is hence anobvious way of improving access of the poor to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>.This may also involve rendering legal jarg<strong>on</strong>into everyday terms in the dominant country language.Policy briefings: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are summary reports that re-339


view the current state of practice and methodologiesand summarize critical issues and implicati<strong>on</strong>s.Policy characteristics analysis: This analysis in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msthe understanding of the re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers, <strong>on</strong> thedimensi<strong>on</strong>s and dynamics of the policy, its originsand where greatest support and oppositi<strong>on</strong> are mostlikely to lie. Its purpose is to provide a systematicunderstanding of the policy that can carry over intomore detailed appraisal such as the political mappingor the stakeholder analysis. It is designed toanswer questi<strong>on</strong>s such as the exact aim of the policy,its implementati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>text, how the public mayreact to change, how c<strong>on</strong>sequential the change willbe (Brinkerhoff and Crosby 2002).Political mapping: Political Mapping is a means<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> organising in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> about the political landscapein an illustrative way. Macro-political mappingprovides analysis of political alliances at themacro (nati<strong>on</strong>al or sector) level, while micro-politicalmapping provides more disaggregated insightsinto the political landscape. Political mapping canbe used to illustrate c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>s of support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the government.Problem Census: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Problem Census is usuallyc<strong>on</strong>ducted in a small group setting, at the localcommunity level, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example. Designed as a n<strong>on</strong>threatening,focused discussi<strong>on</strong> that uses smallgroup dynamics, its objective is to elicit a comprehensiveand ranked census of the problems, real orperceived, of households and the community as awhole as well as the community’s proposed soluti<strong>on</strong>s.This approach gives community members theopportunity to articulate and prioritise the problemsthey c<strong>on</strong>sider need addressing in their community,to discuss them as a group, and then collectively decide<strong>on</strong> which problems to solve (ICMM, the WorldBank and ESMAP 2005).Problem solving studies: Problem solving studiesare aimed at devising tailored and practical soluti<strong>on</strong>sto implementati<strong>on</strong> issues. As <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> MIS above,the design of problem-solving studies should bebased <strong>on</strong> the principles of adaptati<strong>on</strong> to user needs,and availability of resources, user participati<strong>on</strong>, parsim<strong>on</strong>y,and simplicity. (Also see Secti<strong>on</strong> 5.)Problem tree: Problem-tree analysis serves toidentify immediate and direct causes and effects ofa focal problem assisted by graphic representati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> technique helps illustrate c<strong>on</strong>text and interrelati<strong>on</strong>shipof problems as well as possible impactswhen targeting projects and programmemes towardsspecific issues.Social Baseline Study: A base line study c<strong>on</strong>sistsof collecting and analysing baseline data that describesthe social and ec<strong>on</strong>omic envir<strong>on</strong>ment of anarea of interest as well as the characteristics of atarget group. A social baseline study, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example,would observer demographic factors (populati<strong>on</strong>,populati<strong>on</strong> density, age, ethnicity, health, income,etc.), socio-ec<strong>on</strong>omic determinants (e.g. factors affectingincome and productivity, land tenure, accessto productive inputs and markets, family compositi<strong>on</strong>,access to wage opportunities), social organisati<strong>on</strong>(e.g. participati<strong>on</strong> in local-level instituti<strong>on</strong>sand decisi<strong>on</strong>-making processes, access to servicesand in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>), ec<strong>on</strong>omic organisati<strong>on</strong> (e.g. localand regi<strong>on</strong>al businesses and commercial structures,infrastructure supporting ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity, government,and other ec<strong>on</strong>omic/industrial developmentplans <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the area), socio-political c<strong>on</strong>text (stakeholderorganisati<strong>on</strong>s, development goals, priorities,commitment to development objectives, c<strong>on</strong>trolover resources, experience, and relati<strong>on</strong>ship withother stakeholder groups), historical c<strong>on</strong>text (e.g.historical issues and events, migrati<strong>on</strong>, relocati<strong>on</strong>),needs and values (stakeholder attitudes and valuesdetermining whether development interventi<strong>on</strong>sare needed and wanted, appropriate incentives <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>change, and capacity of stakeholders to manage theprocess of change), human rights c<strong>on</strong>text (prevail-340


ing human rights issues and country risks), instituti<strong>on</strong>s(role, governance, resources, capacities oflocal instituti<strong>on</strong>s as well as regulatory framework),cultural background (cultural norms and practicesand places of high cultural value) (ICMM, the WorldBank and ESMAP 2005).Social Impact and Opportunities Assessment: Thisis a process that identifies negative and positive impactsresulting from a given project. It then looksat ways of maximising opportunities that can arisefrom the positive impacts and offsetting or minimisingthe negative effects. Being able to dem<strong>on</strong>stratepositive effects at the early stages of a project facilitateslocal engagement and participati<strong>on</strong> (ICMM,the World Bank and ESMAP 2005).Stakeholder analysis: Stakeholder analysis is designedto identify those interests that should betaken into account when making a decisi<strong>on</strong>. It assessesthe nature of a policy’s c<strong>on</strong>stituents, theirexpectati<strong>on</strong>s, interests, intensity of their interest inthe issue at hand, and the resources they can bringto bear <strong>on</strong> the outcome of the policy. It helps ensurethat the policies are designed in ways that improvetheir chances of adopti<strong>on</strong> and implementati<strong>on</strong>. Inimplementati<strong>on</strong>, it helps build an understanding ofthe relative importance of various groups and therole they might play. To be useful, it is importantthat the stakeholder analysis indicates why interestsshould be taken into account (Brinkerhoff andCrosby 2002).Stakeholder m<strong>on</strong>itoring (household surveys, keyin<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mant interviews): Household surveys providedata <strong>on</strong> spending <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> different kinds of goods as wellas household characteristics, such as age, gender,educati<strong>on</strong> and occupati<strong>on</strong> of family members. Dataobtained from household surveys is particularly useful<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> measuring income poverty and relating it tohousehold characteristics. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y are the most valuableresource available <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> assessing ec<strong>on</strong>omic outcomes,as well as some aspects of opportunity, and<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> understanding how those outcomes are associatedwith household characteristics (Stern, Dethierand Rogers 2005). A key in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mant interview is a<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m of in-depth interview often used in the initialphase of a project and again in evaluati<strong>on</strong>. Key in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mantsare selected <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> their first-hand knowledgeabout the topic of interest. Some of the people whomight be approached in a key-in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mant interviewinclude a community leader, the head of an NGOthat could become a partner, or the leader of a smallbusiness organisati<strong>on</strong>. (See Secti<strong>on</strong> 5 of this chapter<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> further discussi<strong>on</strong>.)Strategic Planning Framework/SWOT/PEST: Strategicplanning is a general management techniqueof defining development objectives, planning toachieve those objectives, and deciding how to knowwhen you have succeeded. Strategic planning beginsinternally, and as it progresses toward detailed activityplanning, it needs to be shared and reviewed bystakeholders. SWOT Analysis stands <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘Strengths,Weaknesses, Opportunities, and Threats’ and is aspecific strategic planning tool used to evaluatethose involved in a project or in a business venture.It involves specifying the objective of the projectand identifying the internal and external factorsthat are favourable and unfavourable to achievingthat objective. PEST analysis stands <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘Political,Ec<strong>on</strong>omic, Social, and Technological analysis,’ anddescribes a framework of macro envir<strong>on</strong>mental factorsused in envir<strong>on</strong>mental scanning. It is a part ofthe external analysis when doing strategic planningand gives a certain overview of the different macroenvir<strong>on</strong>mental factors that the company has to takeinto c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>.Technical assistance: Technical assistance meanstransfer of new knowledge al<strong>on</strong>g with new technologyto others who do not know about it. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> field of technicalassistance may include management, operati<strong>on</strong>ssystems, engineering and other technologies.341


Training (<strong>on</strong> leadership, group work and relatedmanagement issues): This tool covers a variety ofplanned, prepared, and coordinated programmemesto give group leaders and practiti<strong>on</strong>ers in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>they can use to per<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m their jobs better.Travel grants/internships <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> officials: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se allowmid-career professi<strong>on</strong>als and para-professi<strong>on</strong>als toacquire practical knowledge by visiting or serving inorganisati<strong>on</strong>s in <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>eign countries.Web-based support: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internet is an invaluabletool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> disseminating in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> to change agentsand development practiti<strong>on</strong>ers about legal empowermentof the poor.<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>shops: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are structured group meetingsat which a variety of key stakeholder groups,whose activities or influence affect a developmentissue or project, share knowledge and work towarda comm<strong>on</strong> visi<strong>on</strong>. With the help of a workshop facilitator,participants undertake a series of activitiesdesigned to help them progress toward the developmentobjective (c<strong>on</strong>sensus building, in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>sharing, prioritisati<strong>on</strong> of objectives, team building,and so <strong>on</strong>). Stakeholder workshops are used to initiate,establish, and sustain collaborati<strong>on</strong> in policiessuch as <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor (WorldBank 1996).Annex 2: Existing Toolkits:An InventoryAccess to justice<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are several access-to-justice toolkits, focusing<strong>on</strong> different aspects of the justice questi<strong>on</strong>. Am<strong>on</strong>gthe major <strong>on</strong>es are the following:• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Access Initiative Assessment (TAI) Toolkit. 13Although this has been designed with the envir<strong>on</strong>mentin mind, the c<strong>on</strong>cepts are capable ofbeing extended to more general access to justiceissues. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are four categories in the TAI toolkit— access to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, public participati<strong>on</strong>, accessto justice, and capacity development. Moreimportantly, the indicators are divided into law,ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t and effectiveness. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> indicators measurethe presence and scope of the law, its breadthand support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> access and whether it providessufficient guidance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementati<strong>on</strong> and en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement.Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t indicators assess governmentacti<strong>on</strong> taken to provide access, including acti<strong>on</strong>to implement laws. Effectiveness indicators assesswhether laws and government ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts haveresulted in effective access and whether theworld has changed because of the level of accessachieved. Given the focus of legal empowerment,adapted use of the access to justice indicators (<strong>on</strong>all three counts of law, ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t and effectiveness)seems to be the most appropriate.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Office <strong>on</strong> Drugs and Crime of the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s(UNODC) has a Criminal Justice AssessmentToolkit 14 This has separate segments <strong>on</strong> policing,access to justice, custodial and n<strong>on</strong>-custodialmeasures and cross-cutting issues. Given thefocus of legal empowerment, adapted use of theaccess to justice indicators (covering four headsof the courts; the independence, impartiality andintegrity of the judiciary; the prosecuti<strong>on</strong> service;and legal defence and legal aid) seems to be the342


most appropriate.• Although not quite presented as a toolkit, UNDP’sPractiti<strong>on</strong>er’s Guide <strong>on</strong> Access to Justice can beinterpreted as a toolkit 15 This has the additi<strong>on</strong>aladvantage of bringing in a pro-poor angle. ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>meaning of access to justice is interpretativeand c<strong>on</strong>textual. When people think of ‘access tojustice’, they are not necessarily thinking of thejustice system. For example, a UNDP participatorysurvey <strong>on</strong> people’s percepti<strong>on</strong>s of justice inIndia found that slum dwellers prioritised accessto justice with regard to ec<strong>on</strong>omic issues, whereasmembers of marginalised castes highlightedthe social dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of access, and indigenousminorities highlighted the political dimensi<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>e, the potential of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malmechanisms to provide people with a sense of‘justice’ in a particular situati<strong>on</strong> depends <strong>on</strong> thec<strong>on</strong>text, and is just <strong>on</strong>e part of a bigger picture.’• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Asian Development Bank has a few toolkits inthe general law area, but the most relevant <strong>on</strong>e isthe <strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> gender, law and policy 16 .Property rightsToolkits <strong>on</strong> property rights bel<strong>on</strong>g to different categoriesor segments — such as housing, land rights,minerals, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests and intellectual property. Am<strong>on</strong>gthe major <strong>on</strong>es are the following:• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Housing and Land Rights Network (HLRN) ofthe Habitat Internati<strong>on</strong>al Coaliti<strong>on</strong> (HIC) has a toolkit<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ‘housing rights defender’ 17 — ‘At theend of the last century, close to 1.2 billi<strong>on</strong> peopleof the world survived in housing c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s thatwere unhealthy and precarious, including 100 milli<strong>on</strong>who were homeless. At least 600 milli<strong>on</strong> urbanresidents in developing countries, with thesenumbers swelling everyday, already live in housingof such poor quality and with such inadequate provisi<strong>on</strong>of water, sanitati<strong>on</strong> and drainage that theirlives and health are under c<strong>on</strong>tinuous threat.’• USAID has a toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> situati<strong>on</strong>s where there isa link between land rights (or their lack) and c<strong>on</strong>flict18 Today a ‘menu’ of approaches helps facilitatebroader access to land and engenders greaterequality in ec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunity. In the past,land was typically taken from large landholdersand redistributed to the ‘land-needy’ by way ofexpropriati<strong>on</strong>, usually with compensati<strong>on</strong> or channelledthrough land funds. Increasingly, marketmediatedand community-managed ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts arebeing explored, including land rental market facilitati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a parallel USAID toolkit <strong>on</strong> therelati<strong>on</strong>ship between minerals and c<strong>on</strong>flict 19 andyet another <strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ests and c<strong>on</strong>flict. 20Labour rights• Core Labour Standards Handbook, co-publishedby ADB (Asian Development Bank) and ILO. 21• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facilityof the World Bank group has a toolkit specifically<strong>on</strong> the issue of how private participati<strong>on</strong> in infrastructurecan affect the labour market, becauseof fears of job losses and changes in employmentstatus. 22 This is designed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy-makers andpractiti<strong>on</strong>ers, especially in countries where thereis an absence of social safety nets.• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ADB has a toolkit, although it is described asa technical note, <strong>on</strong> labour issues in public sectorrestructuring. 23• ILO: Human Trafficking and Forced Labour Exploitati<strong>on</strong>:Guidance <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Legislati<strong>on</strong> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> En<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement.24• D. Tajgman has edited, Extending Labour <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> toAll <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers: Promoting Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy in Cambodia, Thailand and M<strong>on</strong>golia(ILO, Bangkok, 2006).• Ojeda Avilés, Métodos y prácticas en la soluciónde c<strong>on</strong>flictos laborales: Un estudio internaci<strong>on</strong>al(ILO, Geneva, Dialogue Document No. 13, May2007). [Methods and practices in the resoluti<strong>on</strong>343


of labour disputes: An internati<strong>on</strong>al study]• In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Resources Database, which includescase studies. 25• Labour legislati<strong>on</strong> guidelines (which provide substantiveguidance <strong>on</strong> drafting legislati<strong>on</strong> that iscompatible with core labour standards) features achapter covering elements to take into account inany legislative drafting process. 26• Child <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ers in Asia/ILO (2006). Raising <strong>on</strong>evoice: Training manual <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> advocates of the rightsof child domestic workers. 27• ILO’s Gender Mainstreaming Strategy (GEMS) andToolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Asia and the Pacific includes elementsthat can be applied to law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m processes toensure their gender inclusivity. 28• ILO: Gender Equality and Decent <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g> — SelectedILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s and Recommendati<strong>on</strong>spromoting Gender Equality. 29• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO Gender, Poverty and Employment (GPE)Programmeme has included law re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m as <strong>on</strong>emeans of tackling exclusi<strong>on</strong> that keeps women inpoverty. Its capacity-building and policy developmenttools, used in countries in all regi<strong>on</strong>s, arecaptured in the GPE Package, which is available inEnglish and Spanish (Arabic <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>thcoming). 30• ILO: Sustainable Enterprises. (Report of the Director-General,Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labour C<strong>on</strong>ference,96th Sessi<strong>on</strong>, 2007), and the C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>sustainable enterprises adopted at the C<strong>on</strong>ference(Provisi<strong>on</strong>al Record No. 20), set out featuresof legislati<strong>on</strong> promoting both sustainable entrepreneurshipand protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> labour rights.Belgium, Netherlands, India, Mexico, Hungary,Georgia, Kenya and Belarus. 31 Sec<strong>on</strong>d, there isa parallel and complementary toolkit <strong>on</strong> goodpractices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> business inspecti<strong>on</strong>s 32 that lists outbenchmarks that can be used as guidelines by re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers.Third, there is a guide <strong>on</strong> the design andimplementati<strong>on</strong> of business registrati<strong>on</strong> re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>msat the nati<strong>on</strong>al level, with good-practice casesand examples of re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m from several countries. 33Fourth, there is a toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the simplificati<strong>on</strong> ofbusiness regulati<strong>on</strong>s at the sub-regi<strong>on</strong>al level,with a focus <strong>on</strong> the municipal level. 34• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Secretariat has a Comm<strong>on</strong>wealthYouth Credit Initiative Toolkit to help governments,development agencies and NGOs toimplement micro-credit programmemes. 35• A micro-credit rating toolkit was prepared by theUNDP’s regi<strong>on</strong>al centre in Colombo, based <strong>on</strong> micro-creditexperience in Bangladesh, India, Myanmar,Sri Lanka and Sudan. 36• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Office <strong>on</strong> Drugs and Crime of the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s(UNODC) has an anti-corrupti<strong>on</strong> toolkit, underthe framework of the Global ProgrammemeAgainst Corrupti<strong>on</strong> (GPAC). 37• Transparency Internati<strong>on</strong>al has a range of corrupti<strong>on</strong>-fighters’toolkits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>itoring public instituti<strong>on</strong>sand demanding and promoting accountableand resp<strong>on</strong>sive public administrati<strong>on</strong>. 38Business• Business licensing is often a major barrier to doingbusiness and over-regulati<strong>on</strong> and red tape areassociated with low income, low productivity andlarge levels of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality and corrupti<strong>on</strong>. First,the World Bank group has a business licensingre<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m toolkit, with eight case studies from344


Annex 3: Existing Indicatorsand Indices — An InventoryAccess to justice• Bertelsmann Trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> Index (BTI), withdata since 2004 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 119 developing countries.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> status index (SI) of BTI has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> ruleof law. 39• Business Envir<strong>on</strong>ment Risk Intelligence’s Operati<strong>on</strong>Risk Index (ORI) has data <strong>on</strong> 50 countriessince 1996, with a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceability ofc<strong>on</strong>tracts. 40• Columbia University’s State Capacity Survey hasdata since 1999 <strong>on</strong> 108 countries and has aquesti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the degree to which ethno-culturaland/or religious c<strong>on</strong>flict posed a threat to politicalstability in the country. 41• Columbia University’s State Capacity Survey hasdata since 1999 <strong>on</strong> 108 countries and has a questi<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> the state’s adherence to rule of law. 42• Since 1997, the Ec<strong>on</strong>omist Intelligence Unit(EIU) maintains a database <strong>on</strong> the ec<strong>on</strong>omicand business envir<strong>on</strong>ment in approximately 120developed and developing countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re aresix questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> violent crime, organised crime,fairness of the judicial process, en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceability ofc<strong>on</strong>tracts, speediness of the judicial process, andc<strong>on</strong>fiscati<strong>on</strong>/appropriati<strong>on</strong>. 43• Freedom House has three separate rankings; buttwo — Nati<strong>on</strong>s in Transit and Countries at theCrossroads — are <strong>on</strong>ly applied to a limited numberof countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e that can be used readilyis Freedom in the World, in existence since 1978and currently with a database of 192 countries.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a questi<strong>on</strong> in determining the ranking asto whether cultural, ethnic, religious and otherminority groups have reas<strong>on</strong>able self-determinati<strong>on</strong>,self-government, aut<strong>on</strong>omy and participati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a separate questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> whethercitizens are equal under the law, with access toan independent, n<strong>on</strong>-discriminatory judiciary. Yetanother questi<strong>on</strong> can be included in this accessto justice head and this is about whether there arepers<strong>on</strong>al social freedoms, including gender equality,property rights, freedom of movement, choiceof residence and choice of marriage and size offamily. 44• Since 2004, Transparency Internati<strong>on</strong>al and Galluphave the Global Barometer Survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 69 developedand developing countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are twoseparate questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> trust in the legal systemand c<strong>on</strong>cern with the level of crime. 45• Since 1996, Global Insight’s Global Risk Servicecovers 117 developed and developing countriesand has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> losses and costs of crime. Italso has two separate questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ceabilityof government c<strong>on</strong>tracts and private c<strong>on</strong>tracts. 46• Since 1996, Global Insight’s Business C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sand Risks Indicators cover 202 developed and developingcountries. This has two separate questi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> judicial independence and crime. 47• Since 1995, Heritage Foundati<strong>on</strong> and the WallStreet Journal produce an index of ec<strong>on</strong>omic freedomthat covers 161 countries. This has a questi<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> the size of the black market. 48• Since 1996, Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Management Developmentbrings out a World Competitiveness Yearbookthat has data <strong>on</strong> 49 developed and developingcountries. This has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> whether thelegal envir<strong>on</strong>ment is detrimental to the country’scompetitiveness. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is also an additi<strong>on</strong>alquesti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> whether justice is fairly administeredin society. 49• Since 1982, Merchant Internati<strong>on</strong>al Group Limitedhas data <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 155 developed and developing countries.This has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> legal safeguards. 50• Since 1982, Political Risk Services produces data<strong>on</strong> country risks. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial and ec<strong>on</strong>omic risk345


categories d<strong>on</strong>’t interest us. But within the politicalrisk category (140 developing and developedcountries), there is a law and order questi<strong>on</strong>,divided into two-subcomp<strong>on</strong>ents of law andorder. 51• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> US State Department has a Trafficking inPeople Report, started in 2001 and covering 149developed and developing countries. 52• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Cingranelli-Richards Human Rights Datasetcovers 192 developed and developing countries.It has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> independence of the judiciaryand another <strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> impris<strong>on</strong>ments becauseof ethnicity, race, and political or religious beliefs.53• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank’s World Business Envir<strong>on</strong>mentSurvey has existed since 1998 and covers 80developed and developing countries. This hasseveral questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> access to justice and ruleof law — predictability of changes in rules andlaws, quality of the police, organised crime, streetcrime, fair and impartial courts, af<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>dable courts,c<strong>on</strong>sistent/predictability of courts, en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cementof court decisi<strong>on</strong>s, dish<strong>on</strong>esty in courts and functi<strong>on</strong>ingof the judiciary. 54• Since 1996, the World Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Forum hasbrought out the Global Competitiveness Reportand this covers 104 developed and developingcountries. This has questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> crime,organised crime, m<strong>on</strong>ey laundering (through banksand n<strong>on</strong>-banks), quality of police, independenceof the judiciary, legal framework to challenge thelegality of government acti<strong>on</strong>, settlements outsidethe court system, compliance with court rulingsand/or arbitrati<strong>on</strong> awards, en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>cement of commercialc<strong>on</strong>tracts and use of illegal means to adjudicatedisputes. 55• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank’s World Development Indicatorsdatabase can be used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> female work participati<strong>on</strong>rates, unemployment am<strong>on</strong>g women and femalerepresentati<strong>on</strong> in nati<strong>on</strong>al parliament. Thisgives data <strong>on</strong> 184 countries. 56• Although developed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the envir<strong>on</strong>ment area, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Access Initiative’s (TAI) 148 indicators <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 40countries can also be selectively used. 57 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seindicators are divided under law, ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t and effectiveness.One should probably c<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>on</strong>law indicators, rather than ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>t and effectiveness.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> last two essentially bel<strong>on</strong>g to a tool-kitcategory. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> law indicators are again divided intoaccess to in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>, public participati<strong>on</strong> andaccess to justice. We would propose applying thelast heading, <strong>on</strong> access to justice, in which case,there are 23 questi<strong>on</strong>s to c<strong>on</strong>sider. Questi<strong>on</strong>slinked to free legal aid, government immunity,c<strong>on</strong>fidentiality of in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> government acti<strong>on</strong>and independence of appellate bodies shouldcertainly be picked up.Property rights• Bertelsmann Trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> Index (BTI) has datasince 2004 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 119 developing countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>status index (SI) of BTI has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> privateproperty. 58• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank’s Country Policy and Instituti<strong>on</strong>alAssessment (CPIA) database has data <strong>on</strong> 136 developingcountries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> creati<strong>on</strong> of the databasegoes back to the late 1970s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a questi<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> property rights. 59• Since 1997, Ec<strong>on</strong>omist Intelligence Unit (EIU)has a database <strong>on</strong> the ec<strong>on</strong>omic and businessenvir<strong>on</strong>ment in 120 developed and developingcountries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are two separate questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>intellectual property rights protecti<strong>on</strong> and privateproperty protecti<strong>on</strong>. 60• Since 1996, Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Management Developmentbrings out a World CompetitivenessYearbook that has data <strong>on</strong> 49 developed anddeveloping countries. This has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>whether pers<strong>on</strong>al security and private propertyare adequately protected and a separate questi<strong>on</strong>346


<strong>on</strong> whether patent and copyright protecti<strong>on</strong> isadequately en<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced. 61• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank’s World Business Envir<strong>on</strong>mentSurvey has existed since 1998 and covers 80developed and developing countries. This hastwo questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>fidence in the judicial systemin ensuring property rights and violati<strong>on</strong> ofpatents. 62• Since 1996, World Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Forum has broughtout the Global Competitiveness Report and thiscovers 104 developed and developing countries.This has questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> protecti<strong>on</strong> of financial assetsand protecti<strong>on</strong> of intellectual property. 63• UNDP’s Human Development Report (HDR) hasbeen in existence since 1990 and now covers177 countries. This has data <strong>on</strong> patents grantedto residents. 64• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Property Rights Index (IPRI) isextremely new, 2007 being the first year whenthe index was c<strong>on</strong>structed <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 70 countries.It covers both physical property rights (PPR)and intellectual property rights (IPR) and alsoincludes a third category titled <strong>Legal</strong> and PoliticalEnvir<strong>on</strong>ment (LP), IPRI being obtained byaggregating across all three categories. 65• Centre <strong>on</strong> Housing Rights and Evicti<strong>on</strong>s (COHRE)has been collecting nati<strong>on</strong>al data regardingevicti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> several years. 66 As ‘freedom fromevicti<strong>on</strong>s’ should be the minimum set of ‘protecti<strong>on</strong>s/security’to which any<strong>on</strong>e is entitled, thisindicator is vital to assessing the state of legalempowerment regarding land and property rights.COHRE has also developed a tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>itoringthe ‘Right to Adequate Housing’ which includes asub-index <strong>on</strong> ‘security of tenure’.• Internati<strong>on</strong>al Land Coaliti<strong>on</strong>/CAPRi (Collective Acti<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> Property Rights) are developing an index<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> comm<strong>on</strong> property resources, a crucial issue<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> many rural communities, including indigenousgroups. 67• African Uni<strong>on</strong>, the Ec<strong>on</strong>omic <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Africa,Millennium Challenge Corporati<strong>on</strong>, the UN-HABITAT, and World Bank map land indicators <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Africa. A joint initiative to develop a comprehensiveset of land indicators <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Africa is to be linkedto, inter alia, the African Peer Review Mechanismand the Expert Group meeting will be held <strong>on</strong> 3-4May 2007.• UN-HABITAT Global Urban Observatory has beendeveloping a Secure Tenure Index to m<strong>on</strong>itor Target11 of the MDGs related to the slum challenge.Secure land tenure is the proxy <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the achievementof progress in this target. 68• UN-HABITAT Housing Rights Indicators (HRI)is under development, with the United Nati<strong>on</strong>sHigh <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>er <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Human Rightsand includes an indicator related to security oftenure. 69Labour rights• Since 1997, Ec<strong>on</strong>omist Intelligence Unit (EIU)has a database <strong>on</strong> the ec<strong>on</strong>omic and businessenvir<strong>on</strong>ment in 120 developed and developingcountries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> freedom of associati<strong>on</strong>.70• Freedom House has three separate rankings, buttwo — nati<strong>on</strong>s in transit and countries at thecrossroads — are <strong>on</strong>ly used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a limited numberof countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e most frequently used isFreedom in the World, in existence since 1978,and now with a database of 192 countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reis a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> whether there are free tradeuni<strong>on</strong>s or peasant organisati<strong>on</strong>s or their equivalentsand whether there is effective collective bargaining.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is yet another questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> whetherthere is equality of opportunity, which includesfreedom from exploitati<strong>on</strong> by, or dependency <strong>on</strong>,landlords, employers, uni<strong>on</strong> leaders, bureaucratsor any other obstacle that prevents access to legitimateec<strong>on</strong>omic gains. 71347


• Since 1996, Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Management Developmentbrings out a World Competitiveness Yearbookthat has data <strong>on</strong> 49 developed and developingcountries. This has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> whetherlabour regulati<strong>on</strong>s hinder business activities. 72• UNDP’s Human Development Report (HDR) hasbeen in existence since 1990 and now covers177 countries. Data <strong>on</strong> ratificati<strong>on</strong> of some c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s(child labour, eliminati<strong>on</strong> of discriminati<strong>on</strong>against women, eliminati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced andcompulsory labour, freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> andcollective bargaining, eliminati<strong>on</strong> of all <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms ofracial discriminati<strong>on</strong> can be used). 73• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ILO database can be extensively used. Indicatorsare broadly of two categories: those thatc<strong>on</strong>tain in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> ratificati<strong>on</strong> of selectedinternati<strong>on</strong>al labour c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s, and those thatmeasure specific aspects of work, often linked topoverty/empowerment and the lack thereof. Internati<strong>on</strong>allabour c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s set minimum standards,and in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> ratificati<strong>on</strong> is available<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 180 member countries. 74 Ratificati<strong>on</strong> doesn’tsolve the problem of implementati<strong>on</strong> per se, butratificati<strong>on</strong> in itself signifies political will. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ratified c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> database can be divided intothree broad segments, bey<strong>on</strong>d which there is arich database <strong>on</strong> statistics: 751. Eight fundamental c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s that c<strong>on</strong>cernfundamental principles and rights atwork, such as C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s 29 and 105 <strong>on</strong>eliminati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour, C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s 138and 182 <strong>on</strong> child labour, C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s 100and 105 <strong>on</strong> discriminati<strong>on</strong> in employment andprotecti<strong>on</strong>, and C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s 87 and 98 <strong>on</strong>freedom of associati<strong>on</strong> and right to engage incollective bargaining.2. C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s that provide a basic instituti<strong>on</strong>alframework aimed at protecting againstexploitati<strong>on</strong>, such as C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> 95 <strong>on</strong> protecti<strong>on</strong>of wages, C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> 155 <strong>on</strong> occupati<strong>on</strong>alsafety and health, C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> 81 <strong>on</strong>labour inspecti<strong>on</strong>, C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> 129 <strong>on</strong> labourinspecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> agriculture, C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> 144 <strong>on</strong>tripartite c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>, and C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> 122 <strong>on</strong>employment policy.3. C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s that address situati<strong>on</strong>s thatoverlap with poverty, as, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>149 <strong>on</strong> indigenous and tribal people, 76C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s 97 and 143 <strong>on</strong> migrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>employment and migrant workers, C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>183 <strong>on</strong> maternity protecti<strong>on</strong>, and C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>137 <strong>on</strong> rural workers’ organisati<strong>on</strong>s.Business• Business Envir<strong>on</strong>ment Risk Intelligence’s Operati<strong>on</strong>Risk Index (ORI) has data <strong>on</strong> 50 countriessince 1996 and has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> bureaucraticdelays. 77• Columbia University’s State Capacity Survey hasdata since 1999, <strong>on</strong> 108 countries and has aquesti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the severity of corrupti<strong>on</strong> within thestate and several separate questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> nepotism,cr<strong>on</strong>yism and patr<strong>on</strong>age. 78• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank’s Country Policy and Instituti<strong>on</strong>alAssessment (CPIA) database has data <strong>on</strong> 136 developingcountries; the creati<strong>on</strong> of the databasegoes back to the late 1970s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a questi<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> transparency, accountability and corrupti<strong>on</strong> inthe public sector. 79• Since 1997, Ec<strong>on</strong>omist Intelligence Unit (EIU)has a database <strong>on</strong> the ec<strong>on</strong>omic and businessenvir<strong>on</strong>ment in 120 developed and developingcountries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are three separate questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>orderly transfers, vested interests and accountabilityof public officials. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is a separate questi<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> excessive bureaucracy/red tape. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re isa separate questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> corrupti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g publicofficials. 80• Freedom House has three separate rankings, buttwo nati<strong>on</strong>s in transit and countries at the cross-348


oads — cover <strong>on</strong>ly a limited number of countries.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e that can be used freely is Freedom in theWorld, in existence since 1978 and now with adatabase of 192 countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are two separatequesti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> whether there are free professi<strong>on</strong>aland other private organisati<strong>on</strong>s and whether thereare free businesses or cooperatives. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is alsoa questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> whether there is freedom from extremegovernment indifference, and corrupti<strong>on</strong>. 81• Since 2004, Transparency Internati<strong>on</strong>al and Galluphave the Global Barometer Survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 69 developedand developing countries. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are fiveseparate questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> percentage who believe thegovernment is corrupt, frequency of corrupti<strong>on</strong>,frequency of household bribery, extent of grandcorrupti<strong>on</strong> and extent of petty corrupti<strong>on</strong>. 82• Since 1996, Global Insight’s Global Risk Servicecovers 117 developed and developing countriesand has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> costs of corrupti<strong>on</strong>. 83• Since 1996, Global Insight’s Business C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>sand Risks Indicators, covers 202 developedand developing countries. This has two separatequesti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> whether the necessary business lawsare in place and whether there are outstandinggaps and <strong>on</strong> corrupti<strong>on</strong>. 84• Since 1995, Heritage Foundati<strong>on</strong> and the WallStreet Journal produce an index of ec<strong>on</strong>omic freedomthat covers 161 countries. This has a questi<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> corrupti<strong>on</strong>. 85• Since 1996, Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Management Developmentbrings out a World Competitiveness Yearbookthat has data <strong>on</strong> 49 developed and developingcountries. This has three separate questi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> ease of starting a business, the size of the parallelec<strong>on</strong>omy and bribery and corrupti<strong>on</strong>. 86• Since 1982, Merchant Internati<strong>on</strong>al Group Limitedhas data <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> 155 developed and developingcountries. This has a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> corrupti<strong>on</strong>. 87• Since 1982, Political Risk Services producesdata <strong>on</strong> country risks. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial and ec<strong>on</strong>omicrisk categories d<strong>on</strong>’t interest the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g>. Butwithin the political risk category (140 developingand developed countries), there is a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>corrupti<strong>on</strong>. 88• <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank’s World Business Envir<strong>on</strong>mentSurvey has existed since 1998 and covers 80 developedand developing countries. This has questi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> regulati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> starting new businesses,dish<strong>on</strong>esty in courts, frequency of additi<strong>on</strong>al payments,corrupti<strong>on</strong> as obstacle to business andbribery. 89• Since 1996, World Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Forum has broughtout the Global Competitiveness Report and thiscovers 104 developed and developing countries.This has questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> ease of starting a company,burden of administrative regulati<strong>on</strong>s, percentageof firms that are unofficial/unregistered, frequencyof bribery, frequency of firms making extra paymentsand the extent to which firms’ illegal paymentsor influence impose costs <strong>on</strong> other firms. 90349


Chapter 5 Endnotes1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se internati<strong>on</strong>al agreements include the UniversalDeclarati<strong>on</strong> of Human Rights (UDHR), the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Covenant <strong>on</strong>Civil and Political Rights (ICCPR) and the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Covenant <strong>on</strong>Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Social Rights (ICESR), ILO fundamental C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> freedom of associati<strong>on</strong>/collective bargaining, and eliminati<strong>on</strong> of<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour, child labour and discriminati<strong>on</strong>; and <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> indigenouspeoples, the Indigenous and Tribal Peoples C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>, 1989(ILO C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> No. 169). In additi<strong>on</strong>, there is an internati<strong>on</strong>allyrecognised ‘Right to Adequate Housing,’ which includes security oftenure as <strong>on</strong>e of its six comp<strong>on</strong>ents.2 Two useful approaches to analysing stakeholder interestsin development are DFID’s drivers of change (http://www.gsdrc.org/go/topic-guides/drivers-of-change) and SIDA’s power analysis(http://www.sida.se/sida/jsp/sida.jsp?d=118&a=24300&language=en_US).3 Stakeholder analysis is a standard strategic management tool.It is often applied to development programmes and policies. See,<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example, the Overseas Development Institute’s Tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> PolicyImpact. Start and Hovland. 2004 and Chapter 5 of the Internati<strong>on</strong>alDevelopment Research Centre’s text <strong>on</strong> Cultivating Peace, by(Ramirez. 1999. Also see Bianchi and Kossoudji, 2001.4 ‘Rent seeking’ refers to ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts to get government to createec<strong>on</strong>omic rents, which can then be captured <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> private gain.Ec<strong>on</strong>omic rent is simply extra income that would not exist in acompetitive marketplace. Rent-seeking behavior benefi ts theindividual doing it, but is a loss <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> society due to the ineffi ciencies itcreates.5 Where a country has ratifi ed the United Nati<strong>on</strong>s C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>Corrupti<strong>on</strong> (140 have d<strong>on</strong>e so to date), <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal political commitment(if not true political will) already exists to fi ght corrupti<strong>on</strong>.6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are tools that have been used <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> refugee return andrestituti<strong>on</strong> in the Balkans and in Afghanistan that are useful in thisregard (e.g., Aursnes and Foley 2005).7 This typology is based <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e that fi rst appeared inWils<strong>on</strong>.1973., ch. 16. Similar matrixes are widely used in publicadministrati<strong>on</strong> and development texts (e.g., Brinkerhoff and Crosby2002).8 A side payment is a term from game theory referring to acompensati<strong>on</strong> paid to the game’s loser. Logrolling is the exchangingof political favours to support projects that are of interest <strong>on</strong>ly to <strong>on</strong>eside or the other.9 See <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> example the work of the ‘Barefoot College’ (Social <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>and Research Centre) in Vil<strong>on</strong>ia, Rajasthan, India.10 Development practiti<strong>on</strong>ers wanting to mix and match toolsmay refer to the following easily found toolkits and handbooks: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Access Initiative Assessment Toolkit (www.accessinitiative.org/how_to_guide.html); the World Bank/Internati<strong>on</strong>al Council <strong>on</strong> Miningand Metals Community Development Toolkit (http://www.icmm.com/library_pub_detail.php?rcd=183); the UNDP’s Practiti<strong>on</strong>er’s Guide <strong>on</strong>Access to Justice (www.undp.org/governance/guidelines-toolkits.htm);the Housing and Land Rights Network of the Habitat Internati<strong>on</strong>alCoaliti<strong>on</strong> toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ‘housing rights defender’ (www.toolkit.hlrn.org/English/start.htm); the Overseas Development Institute’s Researchand Policy in Development (RAPID) Toolkits (http://www.odi.org.uk/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/toolkit2.html); USAID’s toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> situati<strong>on</strong>s where thereis a link between land rights (or their lack) and c<strong>on</strong>fl ict (www.usaid.gov/our_work/cross-cutting_programmes/c<strong>on</strong>fl ict/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/docs/CMM_Land_and_C<strong>on</strong>fl ict_Toolkit_April_2005.pdf); the Core LabourStandards Handbook, co-published by the Asian Development Bankand ILO (www.adb.org/Documents/Handbooks/Core-Labor-Standards/default.asp); the ILO’s toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> mainstreaming employmentand decent work: http://www.ilo.org/public/english/bureau/dgo/selecdoc/2007/toolkit.pdf; Transparency Internati<strong>on</strong>al’s corrupti<strong>on</strong>fi ghters’ toolkits <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> m<strong>on</strong>itoring public instituti<strong>on</strong>s and demandingand promoting accountable and resp<strong>on</strong>sive public administrati<strong>on</strong>(www.transparency.org/tools/e_toolkit); the CIVICUS and Aga KhanFoundati<strong>on</strong> resource mobilisati<strong>on</strong> toolkit (http://www.akdn.org/agency/akf_trainer.html). See Annex 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> a comprehensive inventory oftoolkits.11 Available at http://go.worldbank.org/KUDGZ5E6P0.12 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Resources Institute is <strong>on</strong>e organisati<strong>on</strong> that hasdeveloped participatory m<strong>on</strong>itoring and evaluati<strong>on</strong> techniques. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>semay be adapted <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> use in <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor activitiesto help countries track progress (and lost ground), and allow themensure that re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ms actually do lead to empowerment of the poor. Alsosee the Participatory Methods Toolkit prepared by the King BaudouinFoundati<strong>on</strong> and the Flemish Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Science and TechnologyAssessment: http://www.viwta.be/fi les/ToolkitPartAssessment.pdf.13 www.accessinitiative.org/how_to_guide.html .14 www.unodc.org/unodc/criminal_justice_assessment_toolkit.html15 Programmeming <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Justice: Access <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> All, UNDP, 2005, www.undp.org/governance/guidelines-toolkits.htm, especially Chapter 2.16 Gender, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and Policy in ADB Operati<strong>on</strong>s: A Tool Kit, 2006,www.adb.org/Documents/Manuals/Gender-Toolkit/Gender-<str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>-Policy-Toolkit.asp17 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Housing and Land Rights m<strong>on</strong>itoring ‘Toolkit’, 2005, www.toolkit.hlrn.org/English/start.htm18 Land & C<strong>on</strong>fl ict, A Toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Interventi<strong>on</strong>, USAID, 2005, www.usaid.gov/our_work/cross-cutting_programmes/c<strong>on</strong>fl ict/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/docs/CMM_Land_and_C<strong>on</strong>fl ict_Toolkit_April_2005.pdf19 Minerals & C<strong>on</strong>fl ict, A Toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Interventi<strong>on</strong>, USAID, 2004,www.iisd.org/pdf/2004/envsec_minerals_c<strong>on</strong>fl ict.pdf20 Forests & C<strong>on</strong>fl ict, A Toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Interventi<strong>on</strong>, USAID, 2005, www.usaid.gov/our_work/cross-cutting_programmes/c<strong>on</strong>fl ict/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/docs/CMM_Forests_and_C<strong>on</strong>fl ict_2005.pdf21 Core Labour Standards Handbook, ADB and ILO, 2006, www.adb.org/Documents/Handbooks/Core-Labour-Standards/default.asp.22 Labour Issues in Infrastructure Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m: A Toolkit, PPIAF, 2004,www.ebookmall.com/ebook/168641-ebook.htm23 Labour Issues in Public Enterprise Restructuring, TechnicalNote, Asian Development Bank, 2006, available at www.adb.org/Documents/Reports/Labor-Issues-PublicEnterpriseRestructuring/Labor-Issues-PER.pdf24 Geneva 2005.25 http://www.ilo.org/dyn/infoec<strong>on</strong>/iebrowse.search?p_lang=en26 http://www.ilo.org/public/english/dialogue/ifpdial/llg/index.htm27 http://www.ilo.org/ipecinfo/product/viewProduct.do;jsessi<strong>on</strong>id=0a038009ce90d3a489e22af427195a29dfeb2dc51ec?productId=3060350


28 http://www.ilo.org/dyn/gender/genderresources.details?p_lang=en&p_category=NEW&p_resource_id=31329 http://www.ilo.org/dyn/gender/genderresources.details?p_lang=en&p_category=NEW&p_resource_id=30930 http://www.ilo.org/dyn/gender/genderresources.details?p_lang=en&p_category=NEW&p_resource_id=13831 Business Licensing Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m: A Toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> DevelopmentPractiti<strong>on</strong>ers, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank Group, 2006, available at www.businessenvir<strong>on</strong>ment.org/dyn/be/docs/137/LicensingRe<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m32 Good Practices <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Business Inspecti<strong>on</strong>s, Guidelines <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mers, Small and Medium Enterprises Department, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>World Bank Group, 2006, available at www.ifc.org/ifcext/sme.nsf/AttachmentsByTitle/BEEGood+Practices+<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>+Business+Inspecti<strong>on</strong>/$FILE/Bus+Inspect+Book.pdf33 Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ming Business Registrati<strong>on</strong> Regulatory Procedures atthe Nati<strong>on</strong>al Level, A Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Project Teams, Small andMedium Enterprises Department, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank Group, 2006,available at www.ifc.org/ifcext/sme.nsf/AttachmentsByTitle/BEERe<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mBusRegNati<strong>on</strong>al/$File/Bus+Reg+book.pdf34 Simplifi cati<strong>on</strong> of Business Regulati<strong>on</strong>s at the Sub-Nati<strong>on</strong>alLevel, A Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m Implementati<strong>on</strong> Toolkit <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Project Teams, Internati<strong>on</strong>alFinance Corporati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> World Bank Group, 2006, available at www.ifc.org/ifcext/sme.nsf/AttachmentsByTitle/BEESubnati<strong>on</strong>al/$File/BeeToolkit05_full.pdf35 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Youth Credit Initiative Toolkit,Comm<strong>on</strong>wealth Secretariat, 2002.36 http://topics.developmentgateway.org/microfi nance/rc/ItemDetail.do~1053.37 Anti-Corrupti<strong>on</strong> Toolkit, United Nati<strong>on</strong>s Offi ce <strong>on</strong> Drugs andCrime, 2004, available at www.unodc.org/unodc/corrupti<strong>on</strong>_toolkit.html38 www.transparency.org/tools/e_toolkit39 http://www.bertelsmann-trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>-index.de/atlas.0.html?&L=140 http://www.beri.com41 http://www.columbia.edu42 http://www.columbia.edu43 http://www.eiu.com44 http://www.freedomhouse.org45 http://www.gallup-internati<strong>on</strong>al.com46 http://www.globalinsight.com47 http://www.globalinsight.com48 http://www.heritage.org49 http://www.imd.ch50 http://www.merchantinternati<strong>on</strong>al.com51 http://www.prsgroup.com52 http://www.state.gov/g/tip/rls/tiprpt/53 http://www.humanrightsdata.com54 http://www.ifc.org/ifcext/ec<strong>on</strong>omics.nsf/C<strong>on</strong>tent/IC-WBESC<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s55 http://www.we<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um.org56 http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/DATASTATISTICS57 http://research.accessinitiative.org/?module=research.methodology58 http://www.bertelsmann-trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>-index.de/atlas.0.html?&L=159 http://www.worldbank.org60 http://www.eiu.com61 http://www.imd.ch62 http://www.ifc.org/ifcext/ec<strong>on</strong>omics.nsf/C<strong>on</strong>tent/IC-WBESC<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s63 http://www.we<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um.org64 http://www.undp.org65 http://internati<strong>on</strong>alpropertyrightsindex.org/index.php?c<strong>on</strong>tent=home66 http://www.cohre.org67 http://www.landcoaliti<strong>on</strong>.org/programme/polcompropstudy.htm68 http://millenniumindicators.un.org/unsd/mdg/Metadata.aspx?IndicatorId=3269 http://www.unhabitat.org70 http://www.eiu.com71 http://www.freedomhouse.org72 http://www.imd.ch73 http://www.undp.org74 http://.www.ilo.org/ilolex75 Obviously relevant <strong>on</strong>ly if such people exist in the countryc<strong>on</strong>cerned.76 http://laborsta.ilo.org. Employment in the in<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal ec<strong>on</strong>omy,child labour statistics, decent work indicators, <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ced labour andgender discriminati<strong>on</strong> are instances of areas where this databasecan be mined.77 http://www.beri.com78 http://www.columbia.edu79 http://www.worldbank.org80 http://www.eiu.com81 http://www.freedomhouse.org82 http://www.gallup-internati<strong>on</strong>al.com83 http://www.globalinsight.com84 http://www.globalinsight.com85 http://www.heritage.org86 http://www.imd.ch87 http://www.merchantinternati<strong>on</strong>al.com88 http://www.prsgroup.com89 http://www.ifc.org/ifcext/ec<strong>on</strong>omics.nsf/C<strong>on</strong>tent/IC-WBESC<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s90 http://www.we<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>um.org351


Chapter 5 BibliographyAbdul-Jalil, Musa Adam. 2005. ‘Land Tenure and Inter-EthnicC<strong>on</strong>fl ict in Darfur,’ in Report of the C<strong>on</strong>ference <strong>on</strong> LandTenure and C<strong>on</strong>fl ict in Africa: Preventi<strong>on</strong>, Mitigati<strong>on</strong> andRec<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>. Nairobi: ACTS Press.Alsop, Ruth, and Nina Heinsohn. 2005. Measuring Empowerment inPractice: Structuring Analysis and Framework Indicators,World Bank Policy Research <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper No. 3510.Arndt, Christiane, and Charles Oman. 2006. Uses and Abuses ofGovernance Indicators, OECD Development Centre Study.Assaad, Ragui. 1996. Formalizing the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal? <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Trans<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mati<strong>on</strong>of Cairo’s Refuse Collecti<strong>on</strong> System, Journal of PlanningEducati<strong>on</strong> and Research 16 (2), 115-126.Aursnes, Ingunn Sofi e, and C<strong>on</strong>or Foley. 2005. (April) PropertyRestituti<strong>on</strong> in Practice: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Norwegian Refugee Councils’Experience, Norwegian Refugee Council.Barrett, Jane. 2003. Organising in the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Ec<strong>on</strong>omy: A Case Studyof the Minibus Taxi Industry in South Africa, SEED <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ingPaper No.39, ILO.Berg, Janine, and Sandrine Cazes. 2007. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Doing BusinessIndicators: Measurement Issues and Political Implicati<strong>on</strong>s,ILO Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Labour Market Papers 2007/6, Geneva.Bianchi, Robert R. and Sherrie A. Kossoudji. 2001. Interest Groupsand Organisati<strong>on</strong>s as Stakeholders, World Bank, SocialDevelopment Papers No. 35.Brinkerhoff, Derick W. 2000. ‘Assessing Political Will <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Anti-Corrupti<strong>on</strong> Ef<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>ts: An Analytic Framework.’ PublicAdministrati<strong>on</strong> and Development 20 (3), 239-252.Brinkerhoff, Derick W., and Benjamin L. Crosby. 2002. ManagingPolicy Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m, C<strong>on</strong>cepts and Tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Decisi<strong>on</strong>-Makersin Developing and Transiti<strong>on</strong> Countries, Bloomfi eld, CT,Kumarian Press.Brinkerhoff, Derick W., and Arthur A. Goldsmith. 2004. ‘GoodGovernance, Clientelism and Patrim<strong>on</strong>ialism: NewPerspectives <strong>on</strong> Old Problems.’Internati<strong>on</strong>al PublicManagement Journal 7 (2), 163-185._______. 2005. ‘Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Dualism and Internati<strong>on</strong>alDevelopment: A Revisi<strong>on</strong>ist Interpretati<strong>on</strong> of GoodGovernance.’ Administrati<strong>on</strong> and Society 37 (2), 199-224.Bruce, John W. et al. 1996. Country Profi les of Land Tenure: Africa,University of Wisc<strong>on</strong>sin, Land Tenure Center.Cook, Maria L. 2005. ‘Internati<strong>on</strong>al Labor Standards and DomesticLabor Advocates: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Politics of Labor Rights in LatinAmerica.’ Paper presented at the annual meeting of theAmerican Political Science Associati<strong>on</strong> .Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.Cotula, Lorenzo. 2007. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Local Resource C<strong>on</strong>trol.Internati<strong>on</strong>al Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Envir<strong>on</strong>ment and Development.Cousins, Ben et al. 2005. ‘Will Formalizing Property Rights ReducePoverty in South Africa’s ‘Sec<strong>on</strong>d Ec<strong>on</strong>omy’? ‘ <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Land andAgrarian Studies. School of Government. University of theWestern Cape, South Africa.Decker, Klaus, Caroline Sage, and Milena Stefanova. 2005. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> orJustice: Building Equitable <strong>Legal</strong> Instituti<strong>on</strong>s. World Bank,WDR 2006 Background Paper.Eurostat/UNDP. 2004. Governance Indicators: A Users’ Guide.Luxembourg and New York.Fung, Arch<strong>on</strong>, and Erik O. Wright 2003. ‘Countervailing Power inEmpowered Participatory Governance.’ In Fung and Wright,eds. Deepening Democracy: Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Innovati<strong>on</strong>s inEmpowered Participatory Governance. Fung and Wright,eds., L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Verso.Golub, Stephen. 2003. Bey<strong>on</strong>d Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Orthodoxy: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment Alternative, Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Series No. 41,Carnegie Endowment <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Peace.Grindle, Merilee. 2007. Good Enough Governance Revisited,Development Policy Review 25 (5), 533-574.Hart, Stuart L. 2005. Capitalism at the Crossroads: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> UnlimitedBusiness Opportunities in Solving the World’s Most Diffi cultProblems, Upper Saddle River, NJ, Whart<strong>on</strong> School.He, Xin. 2005. ‘Why Do <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y Not Comply with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g>? Illegality andSemi-<strong>Legal</strong>ity am<strong>on</strong>g Rural-Urban Migrant Entrepreneursin Beijing.’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Society Review 39 (3), 527-562.ILO. 2001. Stopping Forced Labour, Geneva, available at http://www.ilo.org/dyn/declaris/DECLARATIONWEB.DOWNLOAD_BLOB?Var_DocumentID=1578._______. 2003. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing out of Poverty, Geneva, available athttp://www.ilo.org/global/About_the_ILO/Mainpillars/<str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ingoutofpoverty/lang--en/docName--KD00116/index.htm._______. 2004. Organising <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Social Justice, Geneva, availableat http://www.ilo.org/public/english/employment/strat/analysis/poverty.htm._______. 2007. Equality at <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>: Tackling the Challenges. Geneva.Available at http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---dgreports/---dcomm/---webdev/documents/publicati<strong>on</strong>/wcms_082607.pdfICMM, the World Bank and ESMAP. 2005. Community DevelopmentToolkit. Available at http://www.icmm.com/publicati<strong>on</strong>s/1342CDT.pdf.Kamunyori, Sheila Wanjiru. 2007. ‘A Growing Space <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Dialogue:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case of Street Vending in Nairobi’s Central BusinessDistrict,’ unpublished Masters <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>sis. MassachusettsInstitute of Technology.Kucera, David, ed. 2007. Qualitative Indicators of Labour Standards:Comparative Methods and Applicati<strong>on</strong>s. Dordrecht:Springer.Le Sage, Andre. 2005. Stateless Justice in Somalia: Formal andIn<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Initiatives. Geneva, Centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Humanitarian Dialogue.Lindenberg, Marc, and Shantayanan Devarajan. 1993. ‘PrescribingStr<strong>on</strong>g Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Medicine: Revisiting the Myths aboutStructural Adjustment, Democracy, and Ec<strong>on</strong>omicPer<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mance in Developing Countries.’ Comparative Politics25 (2), 169-182.Moser, Caroline. 2005. An Introducti<strong>on</strong> to Gender Audit Methodology.L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Overseas Development Institute.Örtengren, Kari. 2004. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Logical Framework Approach: A Summary ofthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory behind the LFA Method, SIDA, available at www.sida.se/publicati<strong>on</strong>s.352


Ouchi, Fumika. 2004. Twinning as a Method <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Instituti<strong>on</strong>alDevelopment: A Desk Review, WBI Evaluati<strong>on</strong> Studies EG04-85. Available at http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/80333/EG04-85.pdfPalacio, Ana. 2006. <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor: An Acti<strong>on</strong> Agenda<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the World Bank. Available at http://rru.worldbank.org/Documents/PSDForum/2006/background/legal_empowerment_of_poor.pdf.Patel, Sheela. 2007. Towards the <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.Available at http://www.undp.org/<strong>Legal</strong>Empowerment/docs/SheelaPatel_towards_<strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor.doc.Perry, Guillermo E. 2007. In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mality: Exit and Exclusi<strong>on</strong>. Washingt<strong>on</strong>,DC: World Bank.Platteau, Jean-Philippe. 2004. ‘M<strong>on</strong>itoring Elite Capture in Community-Driven Development.’ Development and Change. 35 (2),223—246.Pozz<strong>on</strong>i, Barbara, and Nalini Kumar. 2005. A Review of the Literature<strong>on</strong> Participatory Approaches to Local Development <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> anEvaluati<strong>on</strong> of the Effectiveness of World Bank Support <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>Community-Based and Driven Development Approaches.Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: World Bank. Operati<strong>on</strong>s Evaluati<strong>on</strong>Department <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper.Pur, Kripa Ananth, and Mick Moore. 2007. Ambiguous Instituti<strong>on</strong>s:Traditi<strong>on</strong>al Governance and Local Democracy in Rural India.IDS <str<strong>on</strong>g>Work</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Paper 282.Radel, Claudia. 2005. ‘Women’s Community-Based Organisati<strong>on</strong>s,C<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> Projects, and Effective Land C<strong>on</strong>trol inSouthern Mexico.’ Journal of Latin American Geography 4,(2), 7-34.Ramirez, Ricardo. 1999. ‘Stakeholder Analysis and C<strong>on</strong>fl ictManagement.’ In: Cultivating Peace: C<strong>on</strong>fl ict andCollaborati<strong>on</strong> in Natural Resource Management. ed. DanielBuckles. Ottawa: Internati<strong>on</strong>al Development ResearchCentre.Ribot, Jesse C. 1999. Decentralisati<strong>on</strong>, Participati<strong>on</strong> and Accountabilityin Sahelian Forestry: <strong>Legal</strong> Instruments of Political-Administrative C<strong>on</strong>trol, Africa: Journal of the Internati<strong>on</strong>alAfrican Institute, 69 (1), 23-65.Robb, C. M. 2000. How the Poor Can Have a Voice in Government Policy,Finance & Development 37 (4). Available at http://www.fao.org/Participati<strong>on</strong>/ft_more.jsp?ID=2163.Ross, Michael. 2006. ‘Is Democracy Good <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Poor?’ AmericanJournal of Political Science. 50 (4), 860-874.Samuels, Kirsti. 2006. Rule of <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> Re<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>m in Post-C<strong>on</strong>fl ict Countries:Operati<strong>on</strong>al Initiatives and Less<strong>on</strong>s Learnt. World Bank.C<strong>on</strong>fl ict Preventi<strong>on</strong> and Rec<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> Paper No. 37.Schneider, Friedrich. 2002. Size and Measurement of the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>malEc<strong>on</strong>omy in 110 Countries around the World. DoingBusiness project. World Bank working paper. July.Shatkin, Gavin. 2000. Obstacles to Empowerment: Local Politics andCivil Society in Metropolitan Manila, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Philippines, UrbanStudies. 37 (12), 2357-2375.Start, Daniel, and Ingie Hovland. 2004. Tools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Policy Impact: AHandbook <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Researchers, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>, Overseas DevelopmentInstitute.Stern, Nicholas, Jean-Jacques Dethier, and F. Halsey Rogers. 2005.Growth and Empowerment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Tendler, Judith. 2002. ‘Small Firms, the In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Sector, and the Devil’sDeal.’ IDS Bulletin 33 (3), 98-104.UN Global Compact Offi ce. 2007. UN Global Compact Annual Review.New York.UNEP. 2004. Women and the Envir<strong>on</strong>ment. Nairobi.USAID. 1998. Handbook of Democracy and Governance ProgrammeIndicators, Center <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Democracy and Governance,Washingt<strong>on</strong>.van der Merwe, Susan. 2007. ‘A Policy Perspective from South Africa.’In In<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>mal Instituti<strong>on</strong>s: How Social Norms Help or HinderDevelopment. Paris: OECD Development Centre.Varshney, Ashutosh. 2005. ‘Democracy and Poverty.’ In MeasuringEmpowerment. ed., Deepa Narayan-Parker. New York:Ox<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>d University Press.Viswanathan, Sujatha, and Ravi Srivastava 2007. Learning from thePoor, Manila, Asian Development Bank.Wampler, Brian. 2007. Participatory Budgeting in Brazil: C<strong>on</strong>testati<strong>on</strong>,Cooperati<strong>on</strong>, and Accountability. University Park:Pennsylvania State University Press.Wells, A., et al. 2004. Rural Livelihoods, Forest <str<strong>on</strong>g>Law</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the IllegalTimber Trade in H<strong>on</strong>duras and Nicaragua, Research paper<str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> CIFOR, Bogor Barat.Wils<strong>on</strong>, James Q.1973. Political Organisati<strong>on</strong>s, New York: Basic Books.World Bank. 1996. Participati<strong>on</strong> Sourcebook, Appendix 1: Methods andTools <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g> Social Analysis. Available at www.worldbank.org/wbi/sourcebook/sbpdf.htm353


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Legal</strong> Empowerment of the Poor aims to make legal protecti<strong>on</strong> andec<strong>on</strong>omic opportunity not the privilege of the few but the right of all.This is a wholly different approach to thepoverty debate …our <str<strong>on</strong>g>Commissi<strong>on</strong></str<strong>on</strong>g> will focus <strong>on</strong>a unique and overlooked aspect of the problem:the inextricable link between pervasive povertyand the absence of legal protecti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>for</str<strong>on</strong>g>the poor.– Madeleine K. Albright<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> law is not something that you invent in auniversity – the law is something that youdiscover. Poor people already have agreementsam<strong>on</strong>g themselves, social c<strong>on</strong>tracts, and what youhave to do is professi<strong>on</strong>ally standardize thesec<strong>on</strong>tracts to create <strong>on</strong>e legal system that everybodyrecognizes and obeys.– Hernando de Sotowww.undp.org/legalempowermentdesign: cynthiaspence.com

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!