03.12.2012 Views

safeguarding investments in natural gas infrastructure

safeguarding investments in natural gas infrastructure

safeguarding investments in natural gas infrastructure

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

paper series<br />

SAFEGUARDING INVESTMENTS IN NATURAL GAS<br />

INFRASTRUCTURE<br />

LESSoNS LEARNED FRoM REGULAToRy REGIMES IN<br />

ThE UNITED STATES AND ThE EURopEAN UNIoN<br />

Tim Boersma


© 2012 Transatlantic Academy. All rights reserved.<br />

No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted <strong>in</strong> any form or by any means<br />

without permission <strong>in</strong> writ<strong>in</strong>g from the Transatlantic Academy. Please direct <strong>in</strong>quiries to:<br />

Transatlantic Academy<br />

1744 R Street, NW<br />

Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC 20009<br />

T 1 202 745 3886<br />

F 1 202 265 1662<br />

E Info@transatlanticacademy.org<br />

This publication can be downloaded for free at www.transatlanticacademy.org.<br />

Transatlantic Academy Paper Series<br />

The Transatlantic Academy Paper Series presents research on a variety of transatlantic topics by staff,<br />

fellows, and partners of the Transatlantic Academy. The views expressed here are those of the author<br />

and do not necessarily represent the views of the Transatlantic Academy. Comments from readers<br />

are welcome; reply to the mail<strong>in</strong>g address above or by e-mail to Info@transatlanticacademy.org.<br />

About the Transatlantic Academy<br />

The Transatlantic Academy was created <strong>in</strong> 2007 as a partnership between the German Marshall<br />

Fund of the United States (GMF) and the ZEIT-Stiftung Ebel<strong>in</strong> und Gerd Bucerius. The Robert<br />

Bosch Stiftung and the Lynde and Harry Bradley Foundation jo<strong>in</strong>ed as full partners beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><br />

2008, and the Fritz Thyssen Foundation jo<strong>in</strong>ed as a full partner <strong>in</strong> 2011. The Compagnia di San<br />

Paolo jo<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>g additional support <strong>in</strong> May 2009, as did the Joachim Herz Stiftung and the<br />

Volkswagen Stifung <strong>in</strong> 2011. In addition, the Academy received startup fund<strong>in</strong>g from the Transatlantic<br />

Program of the Government of the Federal Republic of Germany through funds of the<br />

European Recovery Program (ERP) of the Federal M<strong>in</strong>istry of Economics and Technology.<br />

On the cover: Gas fields <strong>in</strong> Pennsylvania, United States © Corey Johnson


Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong><br />

Natural Gas Infrastructure<br />

Lessons Learned from Regulatory Regimes <strong>in</strong> the United States<br />

and the European Union<br />

Transatlantic Academy Paper Series<br />

July 2012<br />

Tim Boersma 1<br />

Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1<br />

Relations between Legislatures and Regulatory Authority . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7<br />

Transport Tariffs or Infrastructure Operator Revenues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9<br />

Private and Public Ownership and Investments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13<br />

Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15<br />

References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17<br />

1 Tim Boersma is a Ph.D. Candidate University of Gron<strong>in</strong>gen and research fellow at the Transatlantic Academy, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton<br />

D.C.<br />

Special thanks go to Dr. Machiel Mulder of the Dutch regulatory authority NMa, Dr. Wim Groenendijk and his team at<br />

Dutch Gasunie, Paul O’Donovan and Ia<strong>in</strong> Morgan of British regulatory authority OFGEM, Brian S. White and Michael<br />

Strzelecki of the U.S. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, and Helmut Fuβ of the German Bundesnetz Agentur.<br />

Furthermore, the comments and support of Professor Catr<strong>in</strong>us Jepma and Professor Jaap de Wilde of the University of<br />

Gron<strong>in</strong>gen and Geert Grev<strong>in</strong>g, my supervisor at Dutch GasTerra and his team have been very helpful, as always. Last but<br />

certa<strong>in</strong>ly not least, I would like to thank my colleagues at the Transatlantic Academy and those of the German Marshall<br />

Fund who have provided me with useful comments and feedback, while at the same time contribut<strong>in</strong>g to my wonderful time<br />

<strong>in</strong> the United States.


Introduction<br />

The challenge to <strong>in</strong>terconnect and adapt<br />

European energy <strong>in</strong>frastructure is significant<br />

and urgent. 1 In June 2011, the European<br />

Commission estimated that roughly €200 billion<br />

<strong>in</strong> total <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> were needed <strong>in</strong> energy<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure up to 2020. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>natural</strong><br />

<strong>gas</strong> cont<strong>in</strong>ues to play a crucial role <strong>in</strong> the European<br />

Union energy mix, about €70 billion of that total<br />

amount would be needed for <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong><br />

transmission <strong>in</strong>frastructure, storage facilities,<br />

liquefied <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> (LNG) term<strong>in</strong>als, and reverse<br />

flow <strong>in</strong>frastructure. The commission estimated<br />

that necessary <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> will not take place<br />

under bus<strong>in</strong>ess-as-usual conditions, because of<br />

problems related to permit grant<strong>in</strong>g, regulation,<br />

and f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g (European Commission, 2011).<br />

Regard<strong>in</strong>g regulation, the commission considers<br />

the exist<strong>in</strong>g framework to be “not geared towards<br />

deliver<strong>in</strong>g European energy <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

priorities.” This raises the question of what can be<br />

learned from the United States, which also has a<br />

large market for <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> and has had to deal<br />

with comparable challenges.<br />

Regulatory regimes regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>gas</strong> transmission<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>in</strong> the United States and the<br />

European Union are difficult to compare because<br />

of the myriad differences between the two systems.<br />

But scholars <strong>in</strong> the European Union have looked<br />

at the regulatory regime <strong>in</strong> the United States to<br />

1 In order to give a representation of the regulatory regimes <strong>in</strong><br />

the European Union, <strong>in</strong> this study I exam<strong>in</strong>e the regulatory<br />

regimes of Great Brita<strong>in</strong> and the Netherlands. I do not refer to<br />

the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom <strong>in</strong> this paper, for Northern Ireland has its<br />

own regulatory authority that has not been considered here.<br />

Great Brita<strong>in</strong> has been the front runner <strong>in</strong> the liberalization<br />

of the European energy market. The Dutch are somewhat<br />

beh<strong>in</strong>d, with an advantage of easy access to relevant data. More<br />

importantly the discussion on allow<strong>in</strong>g private funds to have a<br />

role <strong>in</strong> future <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure is contemporary<br />

<strong>in</strong> the Netherlands. For the United States, federal rules apply<strong>in</strong>g<br />

to <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong> transmission <strong>in</strong>frastructure are studied,<br />

particularly those follow<strong>in</strong>g the Natural Gas Act and 1992<br />

Order 636 (A) and requir<strong>in</strong>g significant structural changes <strong>in</strong><br />

the services provided by <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> pipel<strong>in</strong>es.<br />

draw lessons from it. Von Hirschhausen (2008)<br />

concluded that there is little reason for concern<br />

about <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong>, resource<br />

adequacy, and supply security <strong>in</strong> the restructured<br />

U.S. <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> market. Others have found<br />

that, tak<strong>in</strong>g productivity and convergence as<br />

performance <strong>in</strong>dicators, regulation has been<br />

rather successful <strong>in</strong> the United States <strong>in</strong> a data<br />

envelopment analysis of U.S. <strong>gas</strong> transmission<br />

companies (Jamasb, Pollitt & Triebs, 2008). This<br />

paper aims to explore whether there are more<br />

lessons to be learned from the U.S. regulatory<br />

system, <strong>in</strong> particular when look<strong>in</strong>g at how to<br />

secure sufficient long-term <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong><br />

transmission <strong>in</strong>frastructure. Although this topic<br />

has received academic attention before (Von<br />

Hirschhausen, Beckers & Brenck, 2004), there are<br />

several reasons to undertake this analysis now.<br />

Why the European Status Quo is Suboptimal<br />

First, draw<strong>in</strong>g from ongo<strong>in</strong>g research on European<br />

Union energy security, the recent scientific<br />

debate on this particular topic has been focused<br />

on limited resources or unreliable suppliers. The<br />

organization of the European Union <strong>in</strong>ternal<br />

energy market, <strong>in</strong> particular regard<strong>in</strong>g regulation<br />

and energy <strong>in</strong>frastructure, is not as thoroughly<br />

explored. Research on energy regulation appears<br />

to face that same pitfall by focus<strong>in</strong>g ma<strong>in</strong>ly on<br />

efficiency. This is illustrated, for example, when<br />

read<strong>in</strong>g that “...Ideally, the purpose of antitrust<br />

and regulation policies is to foster improvements<br />

judged <strong>in</strong> efficiency terms...” (Viscusi, Harr<strong>in</strong>gton<br />

Jr. & Vernon, 2005, p.9). However, the po<strong>in</strong>t here<br />

is that energy regulation is part of a broader<br />

policy area. Legislatures often serve multiple and<br />

sometimes chang<strong>in</strong>g policy goals, which often<br />

go beyond and/or aga<strong>in</strong>st establish<strong>in</strong>g efficient<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment decisions and deal<strong>in</strong>g with antitrust<br />

issues. In short, as some stated “....economic theory<br />

expla<strong>in</strong>s the way to maximize efficiency, whereas<br />

other societal objectives could not be achieved by<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 1<br />

The commission<br />

estimated that<br />

necessary<br />

<strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> will<br />

not take place<br />

under bus<strong>in</strong>ess-asusual<br />

conditions,<br />

because of<br />

problems related<br />

to permit grant<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

regulation, and<br />

f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g.


There appears<br />

to be grow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

consensus<br />

among European<br />

policymakers<br />

that the exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

regulatory<br />

framework is not<br />

fit to address the<br />

major challenges<br />

fac<strong>in</strong>g energy<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

companies <strong>in</strong> the<br />

decade ahead.<br />

competitive markets...” (Kwoka & Madjarov, 2007,<br />

p.26). Furthermore, transmission system operators<br />

may be required to carry out tasks that are not per<br />

def<strong>in</strong>ition part of the regulatory framework. For<br />

example, the Dutch transmission system operator<br />

is required by law to make provisions <strong>safeguard<strong>in</strong>g</strong><br />

security of supply, 2 while at the same time Dutch<br />

regulatory authorities do not use security of supply<br />

as a criterion when assess<strong>in</strong>g proposed transport<br />

tariffs. 3<br />

Second, practice shows that the current<br />

organization of the European Union energy<br />

market regard<strong>in</strong>g this matter is not efficient. Good<br />

examples are the different tariffs that <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

companies are allowed to calculate for the transport<br />

of <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong> the Netherlands and Germany.<br />

In the Netherlands, s<strong>in</strong>ce 2004, there has been a<br />

s<strong>in</strong>gle <strong>gas</strong> transmission system operator, 4 named<br />

Gas Transport Services or GTS. 5 This is a wholly<br />

owned subsidiary of Dutch Gasunie private limited<br />

liability company, <strong>in</strong> turn owned (100 percent)<br />

by the Dutch state 6 but required by law to act<br />

<strong>in</strong>dependently. In July 2008, GTS purchased two<br />

transmission networks <strong>in</strong> northern Germany,<br />

BEB and EMGTG, from Shell and Exxon Mobil,<br />

respectively. This extended the network of GTS<br />

to Berl<strong>in</strong>, supposedly provid<strong>in</strong>g it with a strategic<br />

position regard<strong>in</strong>g the Nord Stream pipel<strong>in</strong>e<br />

that runs from Russia through the Baltic Sea to<br />

northern Germany. Shortly after the purchase, <strong>in</strong><br />

2 Gaswet, article 10a, sub 1, part a.<br />

3 Note that <strong>in</strong>directly, security of supply does play a role <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Dutch case, as the analysis will show later.<br />

4 The <strong>gas</strong> transport facilities that are not part of the national<br />

transmission system are adm<strong>in</strong>istered by regional <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

companies. In the Netherlands, there are 12 of these companies,<br />

namely Co<strong>gas</strong>, Delta, Enexis, Haarlemmermeer, Inter<strong>gas</strong>,<br />

Liander, Obra<strong>gas</strong>, NRE, Rendo, Sted<strong>in</strong>, Westland, and Zebra.<br />

5 In 2005, the <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>gas</strong> company Gasunie was unbundled<br />

<strong>in</strong>to the commercial company Gasterra and the public<br />

transmission system operator GTS.<br />

6 Represented by the Treasury.<br />

2<br />

Transatlantic Academy<br />

2009 the German regulation authority BundesNetz<br />

Agentur, tasked with adm<strong>in</strong>ister<strong>in</strong>g and approv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the tariffs calculated for the transportation of<br />

<strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong>, decided to lower the maximum<br />

turnover to be achieved by <strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

companies <strong>in</strong> Germany. GTS had to devalue<br />

approximately 5 percent of its total purchase, which<br />

was estimated at about €10 billion. 7 This resulted<br />

<strong>in</strong> a political debate <strong>in</strong> the Netherlands regard<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the spend<strong>in</strong>g of public f<strong>in</strong>ancial means <strong>in</strong> risky<br />

purchases abroad, and <strong>in</strong> addition it is also said to<br />

have negatively <strong>in</strong>fluenced the possible purchase 8 of<br />

the adjacent <strong>gas</strong> network of German mult<strong>in</strong>ational<br />

company Thyssen<strong>gas</strong> Netz (RWE), that had been<br />

put on sale at the end of 2008 under pressure from<br />

the European Commission. 9<br />

Third, there appears to be grow<strong>in</strong>g consensus<br />

among European policymakers that the exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

regulatory framework is not fit to address the major<br />

challenges fac<strong>in</strong>g energy <strong>in</strong>frastructure companies<br />

<strong>in</strong> the decade ahead. This conclusion is based on<br />

the realization that some projects are not tak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

place because they provide higher regional than<br />

national benefits, while others are not because<br />

they use <strong>in</strong>novative technologies with higher risks<br />

and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ties. In addition, there are projects<br />

with externalities that are generally not taken <strong>in</strong>to<br />

account by market demand. 10 All this can be l<strong>in</strong>ked<br />

to broad European policy goals, such as energy<br />

security, the development of renewable forms of<br />

energy, and the promotion of the <strong>in</strong>terconnection<br />

7 For more <strong>in</strong>formation, see the Dutch letter of the M<strong>in</strong>ister to<br />

the Treasury, number FIN/2010/230U of April 12, 2010.<br />

8 As announced on February 2, 2009.<br />

9 This is supported by an official press release of Dutch Gasunie<br />

on March 23, that stated it had no <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> Thyssen<strong>gas</strong><br />

(‘ke<strong>in</strong> weiteres Interesse’) s<strong>in</strong>ce the German <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

climate had become unpredictable through regulatory changes<br />

(‘Regulier<strong>in</strong>g hat das Investitionsklima <strong>in</strong> Deutschland<br />

‘unberechenbar’ gemacht’).<br />

10 See for more details Commission staff work<strong>in</strong>g document<br />

SEC (2011) 755 f<strong>in</strong>al, page 6 and further.


of energy networks. 11 While energy regulatory<br />

authorities currently appear to focus ma<strong>in</strong>ly on<br />

efficiency when sett<strong>in</strong>g tariffs for the transport of<br />

<strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong>, this is remarkable given the broader<br />

policy agenda that looms <strong>in</strong> the background. It is<br />

worth <strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g to what extent the other policy<br />

goals just described are considered when design<strong>in</strong>g<br />

tariff structures.<br />

Fourth, relations between national legislators and<br />

regulatory authorities are not always clear. At the<br />

request of the European Parliament, 12 the Dutch<br />

regulatory authority (and its colleagues <strong>in</strong> other<br />

member states) was granted the judicial status<br />

of an autonomous adm<strong>in</strong>istrative authority <strong>in</strong><br />

2005. 13 In short, the goal of creat<strong>in</strong>g this status<br />

was to confirm the importance of hav<strong>in</strong>g an<br />

<strong>in</strong>dependent regulatory authority <strong>in</strong> the energy<br />

sector and thus depoliticize the work of the national<br />

competition authority. In 2010, this status caused<br />

remarkable friction when the Dutch Trade and<br />

Industry Appeals Tribunal (CBb) annulled the<br />

tariff regulation that the Dutch transmission<br />

system operator GTS had designed <strong>in</strong> accordance<br />

with Dutch government policy. The m<strong>in</strong>ister of<br />

economic affairs laid down several conditions<br />

that GTS had to apply when design<strong>in</strong>g tariff<br />

structures, such as the value of the national<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure system, the terms of depreciation,<br />

and the remuneration of the cost of capital.<br />

However, the Council for the Judiciary stated this<br />

was unlawful s<strong>in</strong>ce the m<strong>in</strong>ister was meddl<strong>in</strong>g<br />

11 As laid down <strong>in</strong> for <strong>in</strong>stance the Lisbon Treaty, 2007/C,<br />

306/01, article 176 A.<br />

12 Report of the European Parliament follow<strong>in</strong>g the proposed<br />

regulation 1/2003 A5-0229/2001, June 21, 2001, page 22.<br />

13 Staatsblad 327, June 30, 2005.<br />

with the competences of the regulator. 14 Under<br />

these circumstances, <strong>in</strong> 2010 the Dutch regulator<br />

proposed a new method of regulation for the period<br />

start<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 2006. 15 While these tariffs have been<br />

published and a “settlement deal” of €400 million<br />

has been proposed by the regulator, 16 both GTS and<br />

the jo<strong>in</strong>t major <strong>in</strong>dustrial consumers have <strong>in</strong>dicated<br />

they are not satisfied and have announced a new<br />

tug-of-war <strong>in</strong> court. This has created <strong>in</strong>security for<br />

the <strong>in</strong>frastructure company and negatively affected<br />

the development of new similar bus<strong>in</strong>ess ventures<br />

<strong>in</strong> the Netherlands. 17<br />

Fifth, <strong>in</strong> the Netherlands there is an ongo<strong>in</strong>g<br />

political debate about whether <strong>gas</strong> networks should<br />

be (partly) privatized. GTS’s limited f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

means to make necessary <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> are said<br />

to have fuelled this debate. The unbundl<strong>in</strong>g of<br />

vertically <strong>in</strong>tegrated energy companies, driven by<br />

the European Commission from the late 1980s,<br />

has always been answered by the argument that<br />

networks should always be <strong>in</strong> public hands <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Netherlands, s<strong>in</strong>ce the secure and stable access<br />

to energy is a major public concern. Hence, <strong>in</strong><br />

a liberalized European energy market, the only<br />

14 To be more precise, <strong>in</strong> 2006 CBb ruled that regulatory<br />

format and exist<strong>in</strong>g legal framework did not fit. Then<br />

M<strong>in</strong>ister of Economic Affairs Van der Hoeven issued a new<br />

policy rule, sett<strong>in</strong>g concrete parameters regard<strong>in</strong>g GTS’s<br />

capital expenditures. Then <strong>in</strong> 2010, CBb argued that the<br />

m<strong>in</strong>ister had imp<strong>in</strong>ged on the <strong>in</strong>dependent decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g<br />

process of the Dutch regulator NMa. See also http://www.<br />

nma.nl/en/documents_and_publications/press_releases/<br />

news/2011/11_21_nma_makes_draft_method_decisions_gts_<br />

available_for_perusal.aspx<br />

15 LJN: BM9470, June 29, 2010. Comparable verdicts were<br />

published on the regulations for electricity TSO and DSO’s <strong>in</strong><br />

that same period.<br />

16 http://www.nma.nl/en/documents_and_publications/press_<br />

releases/news/2011/11_49_nma__dutch_<strong>gas</strong>_transmission_<br />

system_operator_is_to_return_eur_400_million_to_its_<br />

customers.aspx<br />

17 The announcement of new court quarrels published on<br />

November 21 2011 is at http://www.energiekeuze.nl/nieuws.<br />

aspx?id=864<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 3


Several years<br />

later, the<br />

unbundled system<br />

operator GTS itself<br />

appears to be one<br />

of the advocates<br />

of the privatization<br />

of a m<strong>in</strong>ority<br />

share of the Dutch<br />

transmission<br />

system, allegedly<br />

because it needs<br />

additional funds<br />

to make required<br />

<strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong>.<br />

reasonable th<strong>in</strong>g to do was unbundle the <strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

companies. Several years later, the unbundled<br />

system operator GTS itself appears to be one of<br />

the advocates of the privatization of a m<strong>in</strong>ority<br />

share of the Dutch transmission system, allegedly<br />

because it needs additional funds to make required<br />

<strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong>. In addition, <strong>in</strong> June 2011, a European<br />

Commission staff work<strong>in</strong>g paper stated that “...<br />

Investors, such as public banks or <strong>in</strong>vestment funds,<br />

confirmed that transmission system operators have<br />

largely exploited their ability to raise debt capital<br />

and that future <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> will require large<br />

equity <strong>in</strong>jections by private <strong>in</strong>vestors or the State<br />

(<strong>in</strong> case of publicly owned transmission system<br />

operators).” 18 Examples like these demonstrate the<br />

need to exam<strong>in</strong>e privately funded energy networks,<br />

by for <strong>in</strong>stance look<strong>in</strong>g at the United States or Great<br />

Brita<strong>in</strong>.<br />

Sixth, <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure are<br />

both costly and time consum<strong>in</strong>g. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

the current operat<strong>in</strong>g framework is <strong>in</strong> need of<br />

improvement, it should be changed soon, if only<br />

because errors are not easily fixed and because<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors need someth<strong>in</strong>g to go by to make<br />

large and long-term <strong>in</strong>vestment decisions. The<br />

examples above suggest that the debate on <strong>gas</strong><br />

market regulation requires more than a regulatory<br />

economic approach.<br />

Methodology and Limitations<br />

This study comprises a comparative analysis<br />

between regulatory regimes <strong>in</strong> the United States<br />

and the European Union. While there is not a<br />

s<strong>in</strong>gle regulatory approach with<strong>in</strong> the EU, most<br />

member state regulatory authorities seem to<br />

follow the examples set by Great Brita<strong>in</strong> and the<br />

Netherlands (Jamasb, Pollitt & Triebs, 2008), and<br />

therefore this study focuses on these two examples.<br />

It describes the relation between legislature and<br />

18 Commission staff work<strong>in</strong>g document SEC (2011) 755 f<strong>in</strong>al,<br />

page 5.<br />

4<br />

Transatlantic Academy<br />

regulatory authorities and their mandates <strong>in</strong> the<br />

EU, the <strong>in</strong>dividual member states and <strong>in</strong> the United<br />

States. Next the criteria that regulatory authorities<br />

apply when determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>gas</strong> transport tariffs are<br />

analyzed. Hereto the broad energy policy goals as<br />

laid down <strong>in</strong> the Lisbon Treaty are used, i.e. security<br />

of supply, efficiency/affordability and susta<strong>in</strong>ability.<br />

These criteria apply to the U.S. case as well.<br />

In an attempt to quantify these policy goals,<br />

efficiency/affordability is exam<strong>in</strong>ed by look<strong>in</strong>g at<br />

what rates of return regulatory authorities allow<br />

<strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure operators to make, together<br />

with transport tariffs that operators charge for <strong>gas</strong><br />

transmission. Quantification of the other policy<br />

goals is more challeng<strong>in</strong>g. Security of supply/<br />

reliability could be measured by collect<strong>in</strong>g data on<br />

<strong>in</strong>terruptions <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong> flows, but those are not always<br />

available and <strong>in</strong>terruptions can have multiple<br />

causes. Susta<strong>in</strong>ability through regulation could,<br />

for <strong>in</strong>stance, be measured <strong>in</strong> terms of net CO 2<br />

reductions, but no such studies have been carried<br />

out thus far. After exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the criteria used<br />

by regulatory authorities to determ<strong>in</strong>e transport<br />

tariffs, this study focuses on the role of both private<br />

and public funds used <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure and<br />

what lessons can be derived from differ<strong>in</strong>g exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

practices. Both primary and secondary data will<br />

be used <strong>in</strong> this analysis; the former is qualitative<br />

and derived from <strong>in</strong>terviews with representatives<br />

of regulatory authorities and <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

companies, while the latter consists ma<strong>in</strong>ly of<br />

academic contributions, policy papers, and legal<br />

documents. 19<br />

19 Most academic literature on regulation focuses on electricity<br />

and not on <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong>. This probably has to do with some<br />

special characteristics of electricity and the dynamics this<br />

br<strong>in</strong>gs for regulation, see for <strong>in</strong>stance Kwoka & Madjarov<br />

who mention non-storability, low demand elasticity, and high<br />

capital <strong>in</strong>tensity and argue that market clear<strong>in</strong>g is the key<br />

characteristic that makes electricity unique (2007, p.27).


There are some important limitations to the<br />

approach taken here to compare regulatory regimes<br />

of <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> transmission <strong>in</strong> the United States<br />

and the European Union. First, as described, the<br />

regimes are fundamentally different and there is no<br />

s<strong>in</strong>gle approach <strong>in</strong> the European Union. Second,<br />

the U.S. market for <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> is under-researched,<br />

accord<strong>in</strong>g to some because the sector used to<br />

be considered as competitive and there were no<br />

concerns about supplies and <strong>in</strong>frastructure (Von<br />

Hirschhausen, 2008, p.2). Most fundamentally,<br />

this research approach struggles with the<br />

quantification of the policy goals, i.e. security of<br />

supply and susta<strong>in</strong>ability. While the British case<br />

provides a good example that demonstrates how<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ability concerns can be part of regulatory<br />

considerations, more tangible long-term study of,<br />

for <strong>in</strong>stance, realized carbon reduction related to<br />

<strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure would be useful.<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 5


1<br />

In regulation theory, the relationship between<br />

legislatures and regulatory authority is subject<br />

to debate. Although economic theory of<br />

regulation has assumed that legislatures adequately<br />

control the relevant regulatory authority, others<br />

have argued that these are difficult to control<br />

because they have access to <strong>in</strong>formation that<br />

is not available to legislatures and because it is<br />

very costly for legislatures to draft new policies<br />

to redirect regulation (Viscusi, Harr<strong>in</strong>gton Jr. &<br />

Vernon, 2005, p. 391). The agendas of legislature<br />

and regulatory authorities normally differ, and<br />

this can cause friction <strong>in</strong> practice. This section<br />

analyzes relations between legislatures and national<br />

regulatory authorities <strong>in</strong> the European Union and<br />

subsequently the United States.<br />

European Union<br />

With<strong>in</strong> the European Union, the relationship<br />

between national legislatures and regulatory<br />

authority <strong>in</strong> the <strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry is based on Directive<br />

2003/55/EC. Member states are summoned to<br />

designate one or more competent <strong>in</strong>stitutions<br />

with the function of regulatory authority that “...<br />

shall be wholly <strong>in</strong>dependent of the <strong>in</strong>terests of the<br />

<strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry...” 20 The driv<strong>in</strong>g force beh<strong>in</strong>d this<br />

clear separation was the European Parliament.<br />

Regulatory authorities <strong>in</strong> the European Union<br />

are responsible for two activities: monitor<strong>in</strong>g and<br />

ensur<strong>in</strong>g non-discrim<strong>in</strong>ation, effective competition,<br />

and the efficient function<strong>in</strong>g of the market; and<br />

fix<strong>in</strong>g or approv<strong>in</strong>g, at least the methodologies<br />

used to establish the terms and conditions for<br />

connection and access to national networks,<br />

<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g transportation tariffs and terms and<br />

conditions regard<strong>in</strong>g balanc<strong>in</strong>g services. 21<br />

Furthermore, member states may delegate the task<br />

20 Directive 2003/55/EC, article 25, sub 1.<br />

21 Ibid, article 25, sub 2.<br />

Relations between Legislatures and<br />

Regulatory Authority<br />

to monitor security of supply to the regulatory<br />

authority. 22<br />

The broad policy goal from the Lisbon Treaty,<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ability, is not mentioned <strong>in</strong> Directive<br />

2003/55/EC. It is, however, the ma<strong>in</strong> subject of<br />

Directive 2009/28/EC on the promotion of the use<br />

of energy from renewable sources. Both legislatures<br />

and transmission system operators have clear roles<br />

regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> grids and grid codes. 23 Yet<br />

the mandate of the regulatory authority <strong>in</strong> terms of<br />

approv<strong>in</strong>g transportation tariffs, as described <strong>in</strong> the<br />

previous paragraph, does not apply as strictly here,<br />

for “...If significant measures are taken to curtail<br />

the renewable energy sources <strong>in</strong> order to guarantee<br />

the security of the national electricity system and<br />

security of energy supply, Member States shall<br />

ensure that the responsible system operators<br />

report to the competent regulatory authority on<br />

those measures and <strong>in</strong>dicate which corrective<br />

measures they <strong>in</strong>tend to take <strong>in</strong> order to prevent<br />

<strong>in</strong>appropriate curtailments.” 24 The member states<br />

themselves appear to have a decisive say <strong>in</strong> the<br />

<strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> needed when it comes to <strong>safeguard<strong>in</strong>g</strong><br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ability related <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure,<br />

as for <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong>dicated <strong>in</strong> article 16, sub. 4:<br />

“Where appropriate, Member States may require<br />

transmission system operators and distribution<br />

system operators, to bear, <strong>in</strong> full or <strong>in</strong> part, the costs<br />

referred to <strong>in</strong> paragraph 3...”<br />

United States<br />

The roles of both legislature and regulatory<br />

authorities <strong>in</strong> the United States are different than<br />

those <strong>in</strong> the European Union, and are more marketoriented.<br />

This is underl<strong>in</strong>ed by the mission that the<br />

Department of Energy pursues, namely “to ensure<br />

America’s security and prosperity by address<strong>in</strong>g<br />

22 Ibid, article 5.<br />

23 Directive 2009/28/EC, article 16.<br />

24 Directive 2009/28EC, article 16, sub 2(c).<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 7<br />

The agendas<br />

of legislature<br />

and regulatory<br />

authorities<br />

normally differ,<br />

and this can<br />

cause friction<br />

<strong>in</strong> practice.


Basically, the<br />

U.S. Department<br />

of Energy relies<br />

on the market<br />

to safeguard<br />

sufficient and<br />

affordable energy<br />

supplies.<br />

its energy, environmental, and nuclear challenges<br />

through transformative science and technology<br />

solutions. 25 Basically, the U.S. Department of<br />

Energy relies on the market to safeguard sufficient<br />

and affordable energy supplies. The department’s<br />

ma<strong>in</strong> activities are to gather statistics and fund<br />

research on the topics that are mentioned <strong>in</strong> its<br />

mission statement.<br />

The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission<br />

(FERC) is the U.S. regulatory authority at the<br />

<strong>in</strong>terstate level. When focus<strong>in</strong>g on the market for<br />

<strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong>, the FERC deals ma<strong>in</strong>ly with <strong>in</strong>terstate<br />

transmission pipel<strong>in</strong>es and spends an estimated<br />

10 percent of its time on <strong>in</strong>trastate pipel<strong>in</strong>es<br />

(l<strong>in</strong>es tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> from transmission<br />

up to distribution level). 26 Similar to the U.S.<br />

Department of Energy, the FERC has adopted a<br />

laissez-faire approach, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the application<br />

of a competitive regulatory model at transmission<br />

level. The method and criteria used to determ<strong>in</strong>e<br />

transport tariffs and rates of return are exam<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

<strong>in</strong> more detail <strong>in</strong> the next section. Overall, a system<br />

operator can, together with market entities (e.g.<br />

shippers), submit a proposal for a new transmission<br />

pipel<strong>in</strong>e at the FERC, that thereafter consults the<br />

market and the public about the <strong>in</strong>tended project,<br />

controls the proposed rates, and whether third<br />

party access is safeguarded and subsequently<br />

approves of the project (or not). If, at any stage<br />

after construction, tariffs are changed (either<br />

due to construction costs, desire by shippers or<br />

because of other reasons) the FERC has to approve<br />

of these changes. If, however, all parties <strong>in</strong>volved<br />

are satisfied with the status quo, the <strong>in</strong>itial tariffs<br />

can rema<strong>in</strong> unchanged, unless the FERC starts its<br />

25 Quoted from website http://energy.gov/mission on November<br />

25, 2011.<br />

26 Note that the FERC has no jurisdiction at the distribution<br />

level, follow<strong>in</strong>g Natural Gas Act article 717, sub b and c. State<br />

level regulation may apply to distribution networks, but that<br />

does not fall with<strong>in</strong> the scope of this paper.<br />

8<br />

Transatlantic Academy<br />

own <strong>in</strong>vestigation. The basis for this competitive<br />

structure is found <strong>in</strong> 1992 Order 636 that aimed<br />

to “...further the creation of an efficient national<br />

wellhead market for <strong>gas</strong> without adversely affect<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the quality and reliability of the service provided<br />

by pipel<strong>in</strong>es to their customers.” This regulation,<br />

among others, required pipel<strong>in</strong>es to unbundle their<br />

sales and transportation services, provide access<br />

to storage on an open access contract basis, open<br />

access transportation services that are equal <strong>in</strong><br />

quality for all <strong>gas</strong> supplies, offer all shippers equal<br />

and timely access to <strong>in</strong>formation relevant to the<br />

availability of their open access transportation<br />

service, and implement a capacity releas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

program so that firm shippers can release unwanted<br />

capacity to those desir<strong>in</strong>g it. 27<br />

In sum, while <strong>in</strong> the European Union national<br />

regulatory authorities by law have a strong mandate<br />

regard<strong>in</strong>g market function<strong>in</strong>g and sett<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

groundwork for transportation tariffs, monitor<strong>in</strong>g<br />

security of supply and facilitat<strong>in</strong>g susta<strong>in</strong>ability<br />

are matters that may be delegated to the regulatory<br />

authority. As the next section will demonstrate, and<br />

as is shown <strong>in</strong> Table 1, this <strong>in</strong> fact happens <strong>in</strong> some<br />

cases. In the United States, the federal regulatory<br />

authority ma<strong>in</strong>ly monitors market function<strong>in</strong>g by a<br />

laissez-faire approach, while security of supply and<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ability are not part of its mandate.<br />

27 Docket no. RM91-11-002, et al. Order no. 636-A section II.


2<br />

Transport Tariffs or Infrastructure<br />

Operator Revenues<br />

Whereas European regulatory authorities<br />

apply <strong>in</strong>centive regulation for the<br />

(unbundled) pipel<strong>in</strong>e companies, the<br />

FERC promotes competition through unbundl<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

flexible short-term rate sett<strong>in</strong>g, strong property<br />

rights and controll<strong>in</strong>g the abuse of market power<br />

(Jamasb, Pollitt & Triebs, 2008, p.3399). Rate of<br />

return regulation prescribes a reasonable rate of<br />

return on <strong>in</strong>vestment for companies <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure. One of the critiques is that it<br />

conta<strong>in</strong>s few <strong>in</strong>centives to operate efficiently.<br />

Incentive regulation <strong>in</strong> theory is designed to create<br />

<strong>in</strong>centives for the regulated firm to lower costs,<br />

<strong>in</strong>novate, adopt efficient pric<strong>in</strong>g practices, and<br />

improve quality. However, proper implementation<br />

is crucial, for the time path of the price cap must<br />

be <strong>in</strong>dependent of the firm’s actual realized<br />

costs, so that efforts by the firm to lower costs<br />

do not automatically translate <strong>in</strong>to a lower price<br />

(Viscusi, Harr<strong>in</strong>gton Jr. & Vernon, 2005, p.436<br />

and further). In addition, some have argued that<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive regulation results <strong>in</strong> lower quality of<br />

electricity service. This manifests itself <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

duration of service <strong>in</strong>terruptions, not <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

frequency of <strong>in</strong>terruptions (Ter-Martirosyan &<br />

Kwoka, 2010, p. 260). This section focuses on the<br />

forms of regulation applicable to Great Brita<strong>in</strong>, the<br />

Netherlands, and the United States.<br />

European Union<br />

The Office of Gas and Electricity Markets<br />

(OFGEM) applies <strong>in</strong>centive regulation with price<br />

caps <strong>in</strong> Great Brita<strong>in</strong>. The regulatory formula, <strong>in</strong><br />

short, leads to an allowed revenue — derived from<br />

an estimate of the operat<strong>in</strong>g expenditure, capital<br />

expenditure, f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g costs, and taxes for the<br />

relevant period, together with the regulatory asset<br />

value — for the transmission system operator. For<br />

the most recent regulatory period, 2007-2012, the<br />

allowed rate of return was (to the transmission<br />

system operator’s satisfaction) 4.4 percent post<br />

taxes. 28 The regulatory asset value is one of<br />

the <strong>in</strong>centives that OFGEM uses to stimulate<br />

<strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> while at the same time reduc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

operation costs. This is elaborated on <strong>in</strong> the next<br />

section, when discuss<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>centives to generate<br />

appetite for <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong> transmission<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>in</strong> relation to the role of private and<br />

public funds <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong> transmission operation.<br />

Next to <strong>safeguard<strong>in</strong>g</strong> efficient tariffs, the tasks of<br />

OFGEM were recently expanded through new<br />

legislation. Start<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 2004, its mandate has<br />

also been to contribute to the achievement of<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>able development. This was confirmed <strong>in</strong><br />

the 2008 Energy Act, which added to the duties of<br />

the Gas Markets Authority “...the need to contribute<br />

to the achievement of susta<strong>in</strong>able development...” 29<br />

How does this materialize on a daily basis? No<br />

examples have been found <strong>in</strong> the <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> sector,<br />

but <strong>in</strong> electricity transmission, one can th<strong>in</strong>k of<br />

<strong>in</strong>centives that were added to regulation <strong>in</strong> order to<br />

dim<strong>in</strong>ish the release of sulfur hexafluoride (FS 6) to<br />

the atmosphere because of its negative impact on<br />

the climate, and because this particular greenhouse<br />

<strong>gas</strong> is not covered under the European emissions<br />

trad<strong>in</strong>g scheme. 30 Furthermore, the regulatory<br />

authority publishes annual policy documents<br />

conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a susta<strong>in</strong>able focus of its activities. 31<br />

28 See National Grid <strong>in</strong>vestor update from 2006: http://www.<br />

nationalgrid.com/NR/rdonlyres/0C5D350E-3B87-469B-BD80-<br />

73895876C953/13654/NGTPCR4overview15DEC06FINAL.<br />

pdf<br />

29 Energy Act of 2008, part 5, article 83, sub 1c.<br />

30 For more <strong>in</strong>formation, see chapter 11 of http://<br />

www.ofgem.gov.uk/Networks/Trans/Archive/<br />

TPCR4/ConsultationDecisionsResponses/<br />

Documents1/16342-20061201_TPCR%20F<strong>in</strong>al%20Proposals_<br />

<strong>in</strong>_v71%206%20F<strong>in</strong>al.pdf<br />

31 For the most recent example, see http://www.ofgem.<br />

gov.uk/Susta<strong>in</strong>ability/SDR/Documents1/Susta<strong>in</strong>able%20<br />

development%20focus%202011_WEB.pdf<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 9


In the Netherlands,<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive<br />

regulation with<br />

price caps is applied<br />

as a mechanism as<br />

well. The Dutch<br />

Nederlandse<br />

Meded<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

Autoriteit (NMa)<br />

carries out an<br />

efficiency check,<br />

and, based on this<br />

assessment, then<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>es the<br />

total revenues the<br />

transmission system<br />

operator can generate<br />

<strong>in</strong> each three-year<br />

period of regulation.<br />

The operator then uses<br />

these total revenues<br />

to propose transport<br />

tariffs for usage of<br />

its transmission<br />

pipel<strong>in</strong>es. 32 The<br />

reasonable rate<br />

of return <strong>in</strong> The<br />

Netherlands is equal<br />

to the so-called Weighted Average Cost of Capital<br />

(WACC). The NMa calculates a bandwidth of<br />

real WACC values before taxes and subsequently<br />

averages the high and low values to determ<strong>in</strong>e the<br />

WACC. By do<strong>in</strong>g this, the regulatory authority<br />

expects that the network operator receives the<br />

return it needs to operate efficiently, while at<br />

the same time expect<strong>in</strong>g that this return will be<br />

representative for the whole period of regulation.<br />

Note that the WACC is gradually <strong>in</strong>troduced by<br />

means of a yearly correction of the maximum<br />

WACC value or cap (X-factor). Based on yearly<br />

32 Gaswet, article 12, sub 1.<br />

10<br />

Transatlantic Academy<br />

Great Brita<strong>in</strong><br />

Netherlands<br />

Table 1. Focus of British and Dutch regulatory authorities,<br />

<strong>in</strong> terms of Lisbon Treaty broad policy goals<br />

Efficiency/<br />

Affordability<br />

Explicit<br />

regulatory task<br />

Explicit<br />

regulatory<br />

focus<br />

performance, the NMa applies <strong>in</strong>centives to<br />

stimulate efficient operations (X-factor) and<br />

safeguard quality standards that are required by<br />

Dutch law (Q-factor). For the current regulatory<br />

period (2010-2013), the real WACC before taxes is<br />

5.8 percent, 33 whereas this return was 6.5 percent<br />

33<br />

Security of Supply Susta<strong>in</strong>ability<br />

Shared responsibility with<br />

Department for Energy<br />

and Climate Change<br />

(DECC), and active<br />

engagement with UK<br />

government to carry out<br />

Gas SCR *<br />

Shared responsibility with<br />

M<strong>in</strong>istry of Economic<br />

Affairs (though no explicit<br />

mandate) for the NMa,<br />

which plays role <strong>in</strong> design<br />

of new balanc<strong>in</strong>g regime,<br />

<strong>in</strong> order to safeguard<br />

security of supply <strong>in</strong> most<br />

efficient manner.<br />

Explicit<br />

regulatory task<br />

<strong>in</strong> of OFGEM<br />

s<strong>in</strong>ce 2008<br />

No delegated<br />

task for the<br />

NMa<br />

Green = green light for the regulatory authority to engage <strong>in</strong> the referred policy area (for <strong>in</strong>stance affordability)<br />

Red = it does not have a mandate<br />

Yellow = a shared policy doma<strong>in</strong> between legislature and regulatory authority<br />

* The Gas Security of Supply Significant Code Review is undertaken by OFGEM with support of the British<br />

government <strong>in</strong> order to determ<strong>in</strong>e whether reforms to the current <strong>gas</strong> balanc<strong>in</strong>g arrangements and/or enhanced<br />

obligations are required <strong>in</strong> order to improve security of supply.<br />

http://www.nma.nl/images/Bijlage%202%20WACC%20bij%20<br />

Methodebesluit%20Transport%20GTS%202010-2013%20<br />

(2)22-193277.pdf


<strong>in</strong> the period from 2006-2009. 34 The regulatory<br />

authority also advises the government regard<strong>in</strong>g<br />

proposed <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> by the TSO and plays a role<br />

<strong>in</strong> the design of market mechanisms such as the<br />

balanc<strong>in</strong>g system.<br />

United States<br />

In contrast to the European Union member states,<br />

the FERC has made a fundamentally different<br />

choice when it comes to the model of regulation<br />

where rate of return regulation is applied. As<br />

with <strong>in</strong>centive regulation, transmission system<br />

operators know up front what rate of return<br />

will be allowed by the regulator, but provisional<br />

correction mechanisms differ substantially.<br />

Whereas <strong>in</strong>centive regulation provides a safeguard<br />

for yearly adjustments of tariffs follow<strong>in</strong>g, for<br />

<strong>in</strong>stance, an X-factor or the regulatory asset<br />

value, <strong>in</strong> the United States most of the agreed<br />

tariffs are not renegotiated. 35 Instead, day-to-day<br />

regulation has been reported to be “a complex<br />

process of exogenous regulation by FERC, selfregulation<br />

between pipel<strong>in</strong>e and shippers, and<br />

market processes, e.g. for secondary capacity” (Von<br />

Hirschhausen, 2008, p.6). This h<strong>in</strong>ts at a major<br />

problem that has been l<strong>in</strong>ked to rate of return<br />

regulation, namely that it provides weak <strong>in</strong>centives<br />

for firms to reduce costs or adopt efficient practices<br />

(Viscusi, Harr<strong>in</strong>gton Jr. & Vernon, 2005, p. 436).<br />

When judg<strong>in</strong>g over a proposed bus<strong>in</strong>ess case,<br />

FERC by law exclusively exam<strong>in</strong>es efficiency<br />

and market manipulation, as “...all rates and<br />

charges made, demanded, or received by any<br />

34 Note that these rates have only been established <strong>in</strong> November<br />

2011 due to an (ongo<strong>in</strong>g) debate between network operator<br />

GTS, heavy <strong>in</strong>dustry, and the regulator that was expla<strong>in</strong>ed the<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduction. It has led to the status quo <strong>in</strong> which GTS has<br />

to repay €400 million to the users of its network, while the<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry expected over €1 billion. Both parties are not satisfied<br />

with this and more legal tug-of-war has been announced.<br />

35 As confirmed <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>terview with representatives of the<br />

FERC on November 23, 2011.<br />

<strong>natural</strong>-<strong>gas</strong> company for or <strong>in</strong> connection with<br />

the transportation or sale of <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong> subject to<br />

the jurisdiction of the Commission, and all rules<br />

and regulations affect<strong>in</strong>g or perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g to such<br />

rates or charges, shall be just and reasonable...” 36<br />

Market manipulation is excluded by demand<strong>in</strong>g<br />

third party access and fix<strong>in</strong>g tariffs, at any<br />

moment when unreasonable or unjust prices are<br />

identified. 37 Currently, the standard rate of return<br />

that is allowed for a new pipel<strong>in</strong>e is 14 percent.<br />

This number functions as a market <strong>in</strong>centive. If<br />

operators and /or shippers consult the FERC <strong>in</strong><br />

order to change the tariffs of an exist<strong>in</strong>g pipel<strong>in</strong>e,<br />

due to operational costs, compla<strong>in</strong>ts of shippers,<br />

or other reasons, the regulatory authority proposes<br />

a rate of return of 11.55 percent. These pipel<strong>in</strong>e<br />

rate cases are always open to the public. Note that<br />

on the state distribution level, the rates of return<br />

are lower, namely between 8 and 9 percent. In<br />

order to safeguard reasonable tariffs, FERC staff<br />

advocates positions on behalf of the public <strong>in</strong>terest<br />

<strong>in</strong> pipel<strong>in</strong>e rate cases. In addition, FERC has<br />

recently undertaken proceed<strong>in</strong>gs to reduce exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

pipel<strong>in</strong>e rates that it believes are no longer just and<br />

reasonable. 38<br />

The judicial competences of FERC are clear and<br />

focus on efficiency, as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 2. Whereas<br />

<strong>in</strong> the European Union, broader policy goals are<br />

agreed upon and, as we have seen, some regulatory<br />

authorities have them as core competences, <strong>in</strong><br />

the United States these broader policy goals are<br />

not expressed <strong>in</strong> U.S. energy policy documents.<br />

However, the FERC does share strategic goals that<br />

resemble the ones def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the Lisbon Treaty,<br />

such as the Strategic Plan 2009-2014, which states<br />

that FERC’s mission is to “...assist consumers <strong>in</strong><br />

obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g reliable, efficient and susta<strong>in</strong>able energy<br />

36 Natural Gas Act, section 5, article 717C, sub a.<br />

37 Ibid. Article 717C-1 and article 717D, sub a.<br />

38 Data derived from <strong>in</strong>terviews with FERC representatives.<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 11<br />

Whereas <strong>in</strong> the<br />

European Union,<br />

broader policy<br />

goals are agreed<br />

upon and, as<br />

we have seen,<br />

some regulatory<br />

authorities have<br />

them as core<br />

competences, <strong>in</strong><br />

the United States<br />

these broader<br />

policy goals are<br />

not expressed <strong>in</strong><br />

U.S. energy policy<br />

documents.


services at a reasonable cost through appropriate<br />

regulatory and market means...” 39 In practice, this<br />

means FERC works <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with its philosophy<br />

that new pipel<strong>in</strong>e facilities and expand<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

<strong>in</strong>terstate pipel<strong>in</strong>e grid will <strong>in</strong>crease the overall<br />

safety of the <strong>in</strong>dustry (allow<strong>in</strong>g for older facilities<br />

to be abandoned) and hence enlarge reliability and<br />

efficiency.<br />

39 Strategic plan consulted onl<strong>in</strong>e on November 23 http://www.<br />

ferc.gov/about/strat-docs/FY-09-14-strat-plan-pr<strong>in</strong>t.pdf<br />

12<br />

Table 2. Focus of FERC, <strong>in</strong> terms of efficiency, security of supply,<br />

and susta<strong>in</strong>ability<br />

United<br />

States<br />

Efficiency/<br />

Affordability<br />

Exclusive<br />

regulatory<br />

focus <strong>in</strong> the<br />

United States<br />

Green = green light for the regulatory authority to engage <strong>in</strong> the referred policy area (for <strong>in</strong>stance<br />

affordability)<br />

Red = it does not have a mandate<br />

Transatlantic Academy<br />

Security of<br />

Supply<br />

No delegated<br />

task for the<br />

FERC<br />

Regulatory authorities <strong>in</strong><br />

the European Union take<br />

a fundamentally different<br />

Susta<strong>in</strong>ability approach toward calculat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

transport tariffs than their U.S.<br />

federal counterparts. Regulatory<br />

No delegated<br />

authorities <strong>in</strong> both Great Brita<strong>in</strong><br />

task for the<br />

and the Netherlands apply forms<br />

FERC<br />

of <strong>in</strong>centive regulation and<br />

focus on efficient tariffs while<br />

shar<strong>in</strong>g tasks and responsibilities<br />

regard<strong>in</strong>g security of supply<br />

with legislature. On top of that,<br />

<strong>in</strong> Great Brita<strong>in</strong>, susta<strong>in</strong>ability has been an explicit<br />

legal task of OFGEM s<strong>in</strong>ce 2008. In the United<br />

States, the FERC focuses exclusively on help<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the market function, by apply<strong>in</strong>g rate of return<br />

regulation and only occasionally renegotiat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

tariffs as set between system operators and<br />

shippers. The difference between allowed revenues<br />

is remarkable, with European Union rates of return<br />

wobbl<strong>in</strong>g around 5 percent while new pipel<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong><br />

the United States can count on almost three times<br />

that.


3<br />

Private and Public Ownership<br />

and Investments<br />

Theory does not provide a verdict regard<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a preference towards public or private<br />

ownership of <strong>gas</strong> transmission companies.<br />

Although some studies report that regulated private<br />

electric utilities appear to perform more efficiently<br />

than publicly owned utilities, the evidence is not<br />

strong (Viscusi, Harr<strong>in</strong>gton Jr. & Vernon, 2005,<br />

p.508 and further). Others have argued that “...<br />

while often suspected of <strong>in</strong>ferior cost performance,<br />

the evidence here shows that publicly owned<br />

utilities achieve costs comparable to those under<br />

competition. As between those two regimes, public<br />

ownership appears more successful <strong>in</strong> controll<strong>in</strong>g<br />

costs by itself, though regulation buttressed by<br />

benchmark competition achieves a similar result”<br />

(Kwoka, 2006, p.146). A study of electricity markets<br />

<strong>in</strong> Great Brita<strong>in</strong> concluded that “...empirical<br />

evidence on the merits of private ownership and<br />

privatization <strong>in</strong> the context of market-oriented<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure reforms can be characterized as<br />

<strong>in</strong>conclusive. However, when accompanied by<br />

effective regulation, privatization has achieved<br />

efficiency improvements...” (Jamasb & Pollitt, 2007,<br />

p.6164).<br />

A recent study on the relationship between<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment and regulatory regimes (<strong>in</strong>centive<br />

regulation versus rate of return) found not only<br />

that <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> are higher under <strong>in</strong>centive<br />

regulation regimes, but also that there is “no<br />

empirical evidence that private ownership boosts<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>centives” (Camb<strong>in</strong>i & Rondi, 2010,<br />

p.4). This is remarkable, s<strong>in</strong>ce theory suggests that<br />

<strong>in</strong>centive regulation carries the potential risk of<br />

under<strong>in</strong>vestment: reduction of <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> leads<br />

to higher return and can therefore be tempt<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

However, analysis has shown that <strong>in</strong> Dutch<br />

electricity and <strong>gas</strong> networks s<strong>in</strong>ce 2001, <strong>in</strong>centive<br />

regulation has “...ensured a more rational and<br />

professional approach towards <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong>, with<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment levels com<strong>in</strong>g down somewhat at the<br />

start of the regulation but pick<strong>in</strong>g up later on...”<br />

(Haffner, Helmer & Van Til, 2010, p.35).<br />

While the academic verdict on this topic is out,<br />

regulatory authorities are obviously occupied<br />

with the question of how to generate sufficient<br />

appetite for <strong>in</strong>vestment, albeit from private or<br />

public <strong>in</strong>vestors. It seems the FERC has chosen<br />

the path of least resistance, with significantly<br />

higher allowed rates of return to be made on<br />

<strong>gas</strong> transmission tariffs than the European<br />

samples <strong>in</strong> this comparison. In addition, with rate<br />

cases only be<strong>in</strong>g filed when users or operators<br />

br<strong>in</strong>g the case to the regulatory authority’s<br />

attention or when the regulatory authority itself<br />

decides to put a case to the test, <strong>in</strong>vestors have<br />

a reasonable period of certa<strong>in</strong>ty to get their<br />

money’s worth. There is empirical evidence that<br />

there is sufficient <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> transmission <strong>gas</strong><br />

pipel<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>in</strong> the United States (Von<br />

Hirschhausen, 2008, p.7). That leaves the question<br />

open whether the rates of return <strong>in</strong> the United<br />

States will trigger over<strong>in</strong>vestment and <strong>in</strong>efficient<br />

use of capital. The answer may well be “yes.”<br />

With significantly lower rates of return, the<br />

British regulatory authority — like its European<br />

colleagues — has been occupied with the question<br />

how to attract sufficient appetite for <strong>in</strong>vestment.<br />

It boasts about its so-called regulatory asset value,<br />

which is the value upon which <strong>in</strong>vestors earn a<br />

return <strong>in</strong> accordance with the regulatory cost of<br />

capital. It is based on the historical <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

costs and is set yearly, to complement exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

longer term rates of return. In addition to the<br />

asset value, OFGEM is currently work<strong>in</strong>g on new<br />

rates of return, for a longer regulatory period<br />

(2013-2021). The ma<strong>in</strong> reason for this three-year<br />

extension is to provide more long-term security<br />

about the rates of return, i.e. to attract more longterm<br />

capital <strong>in</strong>tensive <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> such as those <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>gas</strong> transmission capacity. As for the Dutch case,<br />

where currently legislature is exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g whether a<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 13<br />

The question [is]<br />

open whether the<br />

rates of return<br />

<strong>in</strong> the United<br />

States will trigger<br />

over<strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

and <strong>in</strong>efficient<br />

use of capital.<br />

The answer may<br />

well be “yes.”


m<strong>in</strong>ority share of the transmission system operator<br />

should be privatized to attract more capital; the<br />

aforementioned experiences <strong>in</strong> Great Brita<strong>in</strong><br />

demonstrate that even when private capital is<br />

<strong>in</strong>volved, attract<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment is a complicated<br />

regulatory task. Extend<strong>in</strong>g the regulatory period<br />

may provide additional stability for <strong>in</strong>vestors.<br />

14<br />

Transatlantic Academy


4<br />

Conclusion<br />

Questions related to <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure are becom<strong>in</strong>g the focus of<br />

renewed attention <strong>in</strong> the United States<br />

and Europe. The European Commission is openly<br />

acknowledg<strong>in</strong>g that the status of the <strong>in</strong>ternal<br />

energy market is precarious and this is one of the<br />

reasons why much needed <strong><strong>in</strong>vestments</strong> <strong>in</strong> energy<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure have failed to materialize. This<br />

paper has given some <strong>in</strong>sights to the challenges<br />

policymakers, regulatory authorities, and <strong>gas</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure companies face <strong>in</strong> the Netherlands<br />

and Great Brita<strong>in</strong> and the possible solutions that<br />

are currently be<strong>in</strong>g explored. It also looked across<br />

the Atlantic to draw lessons from experiences <strong>in</strong> the<br />

United States.<br />

There are several <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g conclusions to draw<br />

from the comparison of transatlantic regulatory<br />

regimes regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure. First, the<br />

cases of Great Brita<strong>in</strong> and the Netherlands show<br />

considerable resemblance. Be<strong>in</strong>g a European<br />

frontrunner when it comes to liberaliz<strong>in</strong>g its<br />

energy markets, the British OFGEM explores the<br />

boundaries of its mandate, e.g. when it comes<br />

to the strict separation between legislature and<br />

regulatory authority as required by European<br />

<strong>in</strong>stitutions. Obvious examples are the explicit<br />

mandate of OFGEM to contribute to susta<strong>in</strong>ability<br />

by means of its regulation (while Brussels<br />

prescribed a clear dist<strong>in</strong>ction between politics<br />

and regulation) or the recent British decision to<br />

extend its regulatory periods to provide private<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure projects with more<br />

long-term stability. In so do<strong>in</strong>g, it has faced<br />

many of the same challenges that other European<br />

regulatory authorities, such as the Dutch, are<br />

currently grappl<strong>in</strong>g with. Second, there is no<br />

under<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> <strong>gas</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>in</strong> the<br />

United States accord<strong>in</strong>g to the FERC and some<br />

academic contributions. This can be attributed to<br />

the substantial rates of return that private <strong>in</strong>vestors<br />

have been allowed to accrue, a mechanism that is<br />

assumed to take care of security of supply-related<br />

issues. Yet it may well be that users of pipel<strong>in</strong>e<br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure and consumers <strong>in</strong> fact collectively<br />

pay too much for their <strong>gas</strong> transport. Furthermore,<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ability does not play an important role <strong>in</strong> the<br />

current U.S. regulatory framework.<br />

More fundamental research is needed regard<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

role of regulation <strong>in</strong> <strong>safeguard<strong>in</strong>g</strong> security of supply<br />

and susta<strong>in</strong>ability. While data regard<strong>in</strong>g network<br />

quality is scarcely available and would provide<br />

guidance for further research, l<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g susta<strong>in</strong>ability<br />

to network regulation is more difficult, for it is<br />

directly l<strong>in</strong>ked to electricity generation and less<br />

to regulation. Hav<strong>in</strong>g said that, <strong>in</strong> Great Brita<strong>in</strong>,<br />

the OFGEM has an explicit legal task to safeguard<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ability and is currently explor<strong>in</strong>g how to<br />

fulfill this role. This is expected to provide future<br />

<strong>in</strong>sights, from which its counterparts on both sides<br />

of the Atlantic could reap enormous benefits.<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 15<br />

In Great Brita<strong>in</strong>,<br />

the OFGEM has<br />

an explicit legal<br />

task to safeguard<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ability<br />

and is currently<br />

explor<strong>in</strong>g how to<br />

fulfill this role.<br />

This is expected<br />

to provide<br />

future <strong>in</strong>sights,<br />

from which its<br />

counterparts on<br />

both sides of the<br />

Atlantic could<br />

reap enormous<br />

benefits.


5<br />

References<br />

Brophy Haney, A. & Pollitt, M. (2009). Efficiency<br />

analysis of energy networks: An <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

survey of regulators. Energy Policy, 37 (12),<br />

5814-5830<br />

Camb<strong>in</strong>i, C. & Rondi, L. (2010). Incentive<br />

regulation and <strong>in</strong>vestment: evidence from<br />

European energy utilities. Journal of Regulatory<br />

Economics, 38 (1), 1-26<br />

Crew, M.A. & Kle<strong>in</strong>dorfer, P.R. (2002). Regulatory<br />

Economics: Twenty Years of Progress? Journal of<br />

Regulatory Economics, 21 (1), 5-22<br />

European Commission (2011). Proposal for a<br />

Regulation on guidel<strong>in</strong>es for trans-European<br />

energy <strong>in</strong>frastructure and repeal<strong>in</strong>g decision<br />

number 1364/2006/EC<br />

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do<br />

?uri=COM:2011:0658:FIN:EN:PDF<br />

Jamasb, T. & Pollitt, M. (2007). Incentive regulation<br />

of electricity distribution networks: Lessons of<br />

experience from Brita<strong>in</strong>. Energy Policy, 35 (12),<br />

6163-6187<br />

Jamasb, T. & Pollitt, M. (2008). Security of supply<br />

and regulation of energy networks. Energy<br />

Policy, 36 (12), 4584-4589<br />

Jamasb, T., Pollitt, M., & Triebs, T. (2008).<br />

Productivity and efficiency of U.S. <strong>gas</strong><br />

transmission companies: A European regulatory<br />

perspective. Energy Policy, 36 (9), 3398-3412<br />

Haffner, R., Helmer, D., & Van Til, H. (2010).<br />

Investment and Regulation: The Dutch<br />

Experience. The Electricity Journal, 23 (5), 34-46<br />

Hirschhausen, von C. (2008). Infrastructure,<br />

regulation, <strong>in</strong>vestment and security of supply:<br />

A case study of the restructured U.S. <strong>natural</strong> <strong>gas</strong><br />

market. Utilities Policy, 16 (1), 1-10<br />

Hirschhausen, von C., Beckers, T., & Brenck, A.<br />

(2004). Infrastructure regulation and <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

for the long-term — an <strong>in</strong>troduction. Utilities<br />

Policy, 12 (4), 203-210<br />

Hogan, W., Rosellón, J., & Vogelsang, I. (2010).<br />

Toward a comb<strong>in</strong>ed merchant-regulatory<br />

mechanism for electricity transmission<br />

expansion. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 38<br />

(2), 113-143<br />

Kwoka, J. (2006). The Role of Competition <strong>in</strong><br />

Natural Monopoly: Costs, Public Ownership,<br />

and Regulation. Review of Industrial<br />

Organization, 29 (1-2), 127-147<br />

Kwoka, J. & Madjarov, K. (2007). Mak<strong>in</strong>g Markets<br />

Work: The Special Case of Electricity. The<br />

Electricity Journal, 20 (9), 24-36<br />

Meran, G. & Von Hirschhausen, C. (2008). 10<br />

Year of Natural Gas Sector Regulation <strong>in</strong><br />

Germany — With Special Focus on Self-<br />

Regulation through Association Agreements<br />

(“Verbändevere<strong>in</strong>barungen”). Zeitschrift für<br />

Energiewirtschaft, 3, 171-176<br />

Ter-Martirosyan, A. & Kwoka, J. (2010). Incentive<br />

regulation, service quality, and standards <strong>in</strong> U.S.<br />

electricity distribution. Journal of Regulatory<br />

Economics, 38 (3), 258-273<br />

Viscusi, W.K., Harr<strong>in</strong>gton Jr., J.E., & Vernon, J.M.<br />

(2005). Economics of Regulation and Antitrust<br />

— fourth edition. MIT Press, Cambridge<br />

Massachusetts.<br />

Vogelsang, I. (2002). Incentive Regulation and<br />

Competition <strong>in</strong> Public Utility Markets: A<br />

20-Year Perspective. Journal of Regulatory<br />

Economics, 22 (1), 5-27<br />

Safeguard<strong>in</strong>g Investments <strong>in</strong> Natural Gas Infrastructure 17


1744 R StReet NW<br />

WaShiNgtoN, DC 20009<br />

t: 1 202 745 3886<br />

F: 1 202 265 1662<br />

e: iNFo@tRaNSatlaNtiCaCaDemy.oRg<br />

WWW.tRaNSatlaNtiCaCaDemy.oRg

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!