13.07.2015 Views

61 Rethinking local government: Essays on municipal reform - VATT

61 Rethinking local government: Essays on municipal reform - VATT

61 Rethinking local government: Essays on municipal reform - VATT

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>VATT</strong> PUBLICATIONS<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>Rethinking</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>:<str<strong>on</strong>g>Essays</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>Antti Moisio (ed.)Valti<strong>on</strong> taloudellinen tutkimuskeskusGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic ResearchHelsinki 2012


ISBN 978-952-274-042-7 (nid.)ISBN 978-952-274-043-4 (PDF)ISSN 0788-4990 (nid.)ISSN 1795-3332 (PDF)Valti<strong>on</strong> taloudellinen tutkimuskeskusGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic ResearchArkadiankatu 7, 00100 Helsinki, FinlandEdita Prima OyHelsinki 2012Kansi: Niilas NordenswanTaitto: Tuula Sal<strong>on</strong>en


ForewordGood <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> governance is essential for an efficient and financiallyrobust public sector as well as high quality public services. Duringthe last decade or so, many countries have aimed at better <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>governance by <strong>reform</strong>ing their <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the fiscalrelati<strong>on</strong>s between central and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> authorities. In the coming years,we can expect to see more <strong>reform</strong>s in many countries, includingFinland, as most countries will have to adjust to ageing populati<strong>on</strong>sand dwindling fiscal resources.This book is about <strong>reform</strong>s that aim to improve <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> governance. Thearticles of this book are written by academic scholars with outstandingexpertise about <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> governance, <strong>reform</strong>s of fiscal relati<strong>on</strong>s and rulesthat steer the ec<strong>on</strong>omics of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> and central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Research Director Antti Moisio from the Government Institute forEc<strong>on</strong>omic Research has led this project and edited the resultingbook with expertise and competence. I want to express my sincereappreciati<strong>on</strong> and thanks to all the authors of this volume: Lars-ErikBorge and Jørn Rattsø from the Norwegian University of Scienceand Technology, Jens Blom-Hansen from Aarhus University, EnidSlack and Richard Bird from the University of Tor<strong>on</strong>to and TuukkaSaarimaa and Janne Tukiainen from the Government Institute forEc<strong>on</strong>omic Research. I also want to thank Tuula Sal<strong>on</strong>en who preparedthe layout of the book.Helsinki, 18 September, 2012Juhana VartiainenDirector GeneralGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research


AuthorsRichard M. BirdProfessor EmeritusRotman School of ManagementUniversity of Tor<strong>on</strong>toSenior FellowInstitute for Municipal Governance and FinanceUniversity of Tor<strong>on</strong>toJens Blom-HansenProfessorDepartment of Political ScienceAarhus UniversityLars-Erik BorgeProfessorDepartment of Ec<strong>on</strong>omicsNorwegian University of Science and TechnologyAntti MoisioResearch DirectorGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research <strong>VATT</strong>Jørn RattsøProfessorDepartment of Ec<strong>on</strong>omicsNorwegian University of Science and TechnologyTuukka SaarimaaSenior ResearcherGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research <strong>VATT</strong>


Enid SlackDirectorInstitute <strong>on</strong> Municipal Finance and GovernmentUniversity of Tor<strong>on</strong>toAdjunct ProfessorMunk School of Global AffairsUniversity of Tor<strong>on</strong>toJanne TukiainenSenior ResearcherGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research <strong>VATT</strong>Post doctoral fellowCenter of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research (HECER)


C<strong>on</strong>tentsForewordJuhana Vartiainen1 Introducti<strong>on</strong> 1Antti Moisio1.1 A <strong>on</strong>ce-in-a-lifetime <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>? 21.2 The future of the Nordic model of decentralisati<strong>on</strong> 41.3 The Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>reform</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>.4 Municipal mergers in a metropolitan area 81.5 Municipal mergers and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> 102 Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesAND the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>se 15Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsø2.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong> 152.2 Fiscal discipline and accountability 162.3 Empirical evidence of comm<strong>on</strong> pool and vertical imbalance 202.4 Intemporal imbalances and deficits 242.5 The Nordic model of administrative federalism 272.6 Fiscal competiti<strong>on</strong> in the Nordic countries 312.7 The future of the Nordic model 343 Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Denmark and the 2007MUNICIPAL <strong>reform</strong> 43Jens Blom-Hansen3.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong> and historical background 433.2 Permanent features of Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>: Electi<strong>on</strong>s,political system, functi<strong>on</strong>s and finances 463.3 The <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s in 2007 523.4 The accompanying redistributi<strong>on</strong> of functi<strong>on</strong>s across tiers 553.5 Reforms since the <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> in 2007 59


3.6 Effects of the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> 633.7 Challenges since 2007: C<strong>on</strong>trolling <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditure 713.8 New <strong>reform</strong>s? The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s 2013 evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the2007 <strong>reform</strong> 774 Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better? 83Enid Slack – Richard M. Bird4.1 Criteria for evaluating <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> governance structures 844.2. To merge or not to merge 864.3 Alternatives to <strong>municipal</strong> mergers 934.4 The case of Tor<strong>on</strong>to: Back to the future? 1034.5 Are there less<strong>on</strong>s for Finland? 1235 Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>?Strategic voting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergers 131Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainen5.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong> 1315.2 Why <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> matters? 1365.3 Instituti<strong>on</strong>al background 1385.4 Data and empirical strategy 1415.5 Descriptive analysis 1465.6 Ec<strong>on</strong>ometric results 1485.7 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s 158


Chapter 1Introducti<strong>on</strong>Antti MoisioGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic ResearchReforming fiscal federalism and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> seems to havebecome almost a comm<strong>on</strong> trend in recent years, both in developedand developing countries. Although the various <strong>reform</strong>s have focused<strong>on</strong> different aspects of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public administrati<strong>on</strong>, they have had <strong>on</strong>ecomm<strong>on</strong> goal: to improve the performance of the public sector. A fewyears ago, the World Bank described very aptly what these <strong>reform</strong>sshould aim at (Shah 2005):“A well-functi<strong>on</strong>ing public sector that delivers qualitypublic services c<strong>on</strong>sistent with citizen preferences and thatfosters private market-led growth while managing fiscalresources prudently”.A recent OECD study lists factors that determine the success of<strong>reform</strong>s for fiscal relati<strong>on</strong>s and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> (Blöchliger andVammalle 2012). Transiti<strong>on</strong>al compensati<strong>on</strong>s and the bundling ofvarious elements are almost necessary requirements for <strong>reform</strong>s tobe successful. Also, favourable ec<strong>on</strong>omic and fiscal c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s andelectoral mandates are important drivers of <strong>reform</strong>s. Using externalexpertise in planning <strong>reform</strong>s is also listed as <strong>on</strong>e important elementfor success.This book builds solely <strong>on</strong> independent and external expertise. Thebook c<strong>on</strong>sists of four original essays by seven authors, who areall acknowledged academic experts in the topics covered by thisvolume. The main aim of the book is to give the reader an insight1


Introducti<strong>on</strong>into fiscal federalism and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>reform</strong>s by discussing thefuture of decentralisati<strong>on</strong> policies, by describing the reas<strong>on</strong>s for andeffects of <strong>municipal</strong> mergers and by analysing alternative models ofmetropolitan governance. These are themes that are currently topicalin many countries, not least in the Nordic countries, and they areespecially topical in Finland.This introducti<strong>on</strong> first provides a short descripti<strong>on</strong> of the presentsituati<strong>on</strong> of Finnish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the <strong>reform</strong>s that lie ahead.There then follows a brief summary of each essay.1.1 A <strong>on</strong>ce-in-a-lifetime <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>?Finnish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sists of <strong>municipal</strong>ities and joint<strong>municipal</strong> authorities. This single-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> is resp<strong>on</strong>siblefor a wide range of public services, such as health care, social welfareand educati<strong>on</strong> services. Due to these significant resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities,<strong>municipal</strong> spending amounts to 65 per cent of total public c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>expenditure and 18 per cent of GDP.In Finland, all <strong>municipal</strong>ities irrespective of their populati<strong>on</strong> sizeare obliged to provide the same services to their inhabitants. Sincethe smallest <strong>municipal</strong>ities usually lack the capacity to provide theseservices al<strong>on</strong>e, small <strong>municipal</strong>ities are often involved in inter<strong>municipal</strong>cooperati<strong>on</strong>, especially within health care. Municipalcooperati<strong>on</strong> has been a successful way to solve many of the scale andexternality problems in public services. The main problems identifiedwith joint <strong>municipal</strong> authorities include a lack of transparency andaccountability in decisi<strong>on</strong>-making, and the gradual shift of decisi<strong>on</strong>makingpower from elected politicians to professi<strong>on</strong>als.At the moment it seems that the Finnish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> sectoris about to face unprecedented changes. Central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> isdetermined to push through a <strong>reform</strong> so as to increase the size of<strong>municipal</strong>ities through <strong>municipal</strong> mergers and to significantly alter<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> service resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities by 2015. The “str<strong>on</strong>g <strong>municipal</strong>ity” plan2


Antti Moisioaims to create <strong>municipal</strong>ities that are able to bear the increasing serviceburden of an ageing populati<strong>on</strong> in coming decades. The str<strong>on</strong>ger<strong>municipal</strong>ities are also expected to take <strong>on</strong> more tasks, since underto the plan the present 20 hospital districts will be closed down andsome of the more demanding health services will be transferred to the<strong>municipal</strong>ities. The most advanced health care would be centralised infive special health care districts. Until now, <strong>municipal</strong>ities have beendirectly resp<strong>on</strong>sible <strong>on</strong>ly for basic health care, as hospital serviceshave been provided by hospital districts, owned by joint <strong>municipal</strong>authorities. The proposed “str<strong>on</strong>g <strong>municipal</strong>ity” model is expectedto result in less need for equalisati<strong>on</strong> between <strong>municipal</strong>ities, sincethe enlarged <strong>municipal</strong>ities will – by definiti<strong>on</strong> – be ec<strong>on</strong>omicallystr<strong>on</strong>ger than the existing <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Therefore, the central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grant system will also be <strong>reform</strong>ed by 2015.The <strong>municipal</strong>ities have str<strong>on</strong>gly resisted the <strong>reform</strong>. The results ofa recent survey of <strong>municipal</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong>-makers show that althoughmost <strong>municipal</strong>ities agree with the need for <strong>reform</strong>s in general, themajority of them still reject the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> proposals fornew <strong>municipal</strong>ities. The resp<strong>on</strong>dents feel that the new proposed<strong>municipal</strong>ities are simply too big. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the proposal to abolishthe present hospital districts has raised c<strong>on</strong>cerns about the ability of the<strong>municipal</strong>ities to organise the most demanding health care services.For example, the largest hospital district, the Hospital District ofHelsinki and Uusimaa, which is the joint <strong>municipal</strong> authority of26 <strong>municipal</strong>ities in the Greater Helsinki regi<strong>on</strong> and surroundings,has been critical of the plan if it leads the joint authority being brokenup.Despite of central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s commitment to proceed with the“str<strong>on</strong>g <strong>municipal</strong>ity” model, alternatives also seem to be still “<strong>on</strong>the table”. The main alternatives include centralised health care or anew regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> tier for health and welfare services. It hasalso been argued – by central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> too – that different partsof the country may need different types of soluti<strong>on</strong>s. One exampleof an area that may be in need of a tailored soluti<strong>on</strong> is the Helsinkiregi<strong>on</strong>, where the debate has c<strong>on</strong>centrated <strong>on</strong> two opti<strong>on</strong>s: the merger3


Introducti<strong>on</strong>of the three biggest cities (Helsinki, Espoo and Vantaa) and the “twotier”alternative. In the Helsinki regi<strong>on</strong>, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities alreadycooperate in health care, so the discussi<strong>on</strong> about a possible new twotiermodel has been mostly about land use and planning tasks.Finland is by no means al<strong>on</strong>e in its plans for <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>.Similar processes have been faced in many other countries. TheNordic countries, which often form the best reference group forFinland, all carried out major <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>s back in the 1960sand 1970s. Despite this, a further <strong>reform</strong> was carried out in Denmarkin 2007, and in Norway the tasks of central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and theregi<strong>on</strong>s were redistributed in 2002. A similar discussi<strong>on</strong> is also going<strong>on</strong> in Sweden. Metropolitan governance seems to have been less ofan issue in the other Nordic countries, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to Finland, wherethe metropolitan area around the capital city has an unusually largerole. However, there are many recent examples in the EU and OECDcountries of <strong>reform</strong>s of metropolitan governance.1.2 The future of the Nordic model ofdecentralisati<strong>on</strong>The sec<strong>on</strong>d chapter of the book, written by Lars-Erik Borge and JørnRattsø, focuses <strong>on</strong> the future of decentralisati<strong>on</strong> policy in the Nordicwelfare state. The article is based <strong>on</strong> a thorough summary of the latestdevelopments in the fiscal federalism theory and empirical research.The authors discuss the differences between fiscal federalism asdescribed in standard ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory and the systems applied inpractice in the Nordic countries. The Nordic countries have devolvedmany public service tasks at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level, and have at the sametime increased central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trol over <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.This decentralisati<strong>on</strong> policy has been justified <strong>on</strong> grounds of publicsector efficiency, and of enhanced democratic c<strong>on</strong>trol of publicservices. Central c<strong>on</strong>trol has been justified by equity c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>sand by <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal discipline and accountability targets. It is clearthat the decentralisati<strong>on</strong> practised in the Nordic countries differsc<strong>on</strong>siderably from the so-called Musgrave-Oates-Tiebout model4


Antti Moisioof fiscal federalism, which is based <strong>on</strong> assumpti<strong>on</strong>s of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> publicgoods, benefit taxati<strong>on</strong>, mobility and no spillovers. Therefore, Borgeand Rattsø prefer to call the Nordic model administrative federalismrather than fiscal federalism.Central c<strong>on</strong>trol and involvement can be seen as a threat to the basicvalues of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-rule and democracy, and at times all the Nordiccountries have tried to limit centrally set norms and regulati<strong>on</strong>s.Although favouring <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> aut<strong>on</strong>omy in general, and acknowledgingthe benefits of yardstick competiti<strong>on</strong>, which has also proved its worthin the Nordic countries, Borge and Rattsø c<strong>on</strong>clude that preventivecentral <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> measures and c<strong>on</strong>trol at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level are neededin order to secure fiscal balances and to avoid bailouts.Borge and Rattsø make an interesting point when observing that<strong>reform</strong>s of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> structure have returned to the policyagenda in many countries, mainly because the benefits of adjustmentsto central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trol systems and grant systems have becomesmaller. The authors think that the future model of federalism willdepend mainly <strong>on</strong> the future organizati<strong>on</strong> of welfare services. Theauthors see two possible paths, <strong>on</strong>e that is based <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> provisi<strong>on</strong>(a renewed model of administrative federalism) and the other where<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>centrates <strong>on</strong> the provisi<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods(a Nordic model of fiscal federalism).A renewed model of administrative federalism would require largerand str<strong>on</strong>ger <strong>municipal</strong>ities, especially in countries like Norway andFinland. In other words, a nati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>reform</strong> of <strong>municipal</strong> mergerswould be needed for <strong>municipal</strong>ities to be able to maintain theirpresent tasks and take <strong>on</strong> new <strong>on</strong>es. Borge and Rattsø list severaladvantages resulting from strengthened <strong>municipal</strong>ities, such asthe ability to c<strong>on</strong>tinue decentralisati<strong>on</strong> in the provisi<strong>on</strong> of publicservices, reduced variati<strong>on</strong> in tax bases and spending needs, smallerdependence <strong>on</strong> central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grants, improved <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracyand accountability, better utilisati<strong>on</strong> of ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale, the abilityto build solid groups of specialists and increased political power inthe <strong>municipal</strong> tier.5


Introducti<strong>on</strong>The sec<strong>on</strong>d opti<strong>on</strong>, a Nordic model of fiscal federalism, would meanreturning to the roots of fiscal federalism, as <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> wouldc<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>on</strong> tasks that are truly <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> in nature. If the burden ofwelfare services is lifted off the shoulders of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sector,the need for large <strong>municipal</strong>ities is reduced. Borge and Rattsø evensee the possibility of break-ups of <strong>municipal</strong>ities in some urban areas.There would be less need for equalisati<strong>on</strong> and <strong>municipal</strong>ities wouldbe less dependent <strong>on</strong> central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grants. Central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>would take resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for welfare services, and this would permitan increased focus <strong>on</strong> equality. However, a new system of governancewould also require resources. New bureaucracy and inefficiencycould emerge. According to Borge and Rattsø, the experiences fromthe Norwegian hospital <strong>reform</strong> serve as a warning example of failedcentralisati<strong>on</strong>.The authors’ assessment of the situati<strong>on</strong> in the Nordic countries isthat the Nordic model of fiscal federalism is less likely to prevail.Therefore, whether we like it or not, <strong>municipal</strong> mergers will be partof the soluti<strong>on</strong> in securing the future of the Nordic welfare state.1.3 The Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>reform</strong>sThe third chapter, written by Jens Blom-Hansen, describes anddiscusses the <strong>reform</strong>s of Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> during the lastdecade or so. The biggest adjustment, the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>,meant a sharp reducti<strong>on</strong> in the number of <strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s.The <strong>reform</strong> also resulted in a c<strong>on</strong>siderable redistributi<strong>on</strong> of tasksbetween the two <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> tiers and central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.The need for <strong>reform</strong> was first investigated by an expert committee.The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> then made a political analysis of the <strong>reform</strong>opti<strong>on</strong>s, c<strong>on</strong>cluding that amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s were needed to reach thetarget <strong>municipal</strong> size of 30,000 inhabitants. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> planthat followed gave <strong>municipal</strong>ities <strong>on</strong>ly six m<strong>on</strong>ths to find a partnereither for merger or cooperati<strong>on</strong>. To the surprise of many observers,the <strong>reform</strong> was completed within the set time limit. Moreover,most <strong>municipal</strong>ities chose to merge instead of entering into deeper6


Antti Moisiocooperati<strong>on</strong>. Another surprise was that the new <strong>municipal</strong>itiesended up being much larger than expected, since after the <strong>reform</strong>the average <strong>municipal</strong> populati<strong>on</strong> size was above 50,000. The whole<strong>reform</strong> process from the appointment of the expert committee untilthe start-up of the new <strong>municipal</strong>ities took four and a half years.According to Blom-Hansen, the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> was thoroughlyplanned, with special attenti<strong>on</strong> paid to pre-merger spending and debt.Several limits to <strong>municipal</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong>-making were set, with a promiseto lift the restricti<strong>on</strong>s from 2007. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> kept its promiseand aband<strong>on</strong>ed the restricti<strong>on</strong>s, but the rapid increase in <strong>municipal</strong>spending and deviati<strong>on</strong>s from the nati<strong>on</strong>ally agreed general spendingand taxati<strong>on</strong> targets forced central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> to restore theregulati<strong>on</strong>s already in 2008. At present, central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> imposesrules <strong>on</strong> <strong>municipal</strong>ities including sancti<strong>on</strong>s such as grant cuts to<strong>municipal</strong>ities that fail to follow their expenditure growth and tax ratelimitati<strong>on</strong>s. Both individual and collective sancti<strong>on</strong> elements are used.As a result, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities no l<strong>on</strong>ger deviate from the nati<strong>on</strong>allyagreed targets and even some expenditure cuts have been seen inthe <strong>municipal</strong>ities since 2009. This has not come about without cost,however. Blom-Hansen argues that the present situati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>stitutes aremarkable break with the Danish traditi<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> aut<strong>on</strong>omy. It willbe seen whether the regulati<strong>on</strong> has come to stay or whether the ruleswill be gradually lifted.The 2007 <strong>reform</strong> stripped the regi<strong>on</strong>s of many of their previous tasks.Also, the number of regi<strong>on</strong>s was reduced from 14 to five. The maintask of the regi<strong>on</strong>s before the <strong>reform</strong>, health care, was maintainedas a regi<strong>on</strong>al task. Some health care functi<strong>on</strong>s were neverthelesstransferred to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities, and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities were alsomade financially co-resp<strong>on</strong>sible for hospital services. In additi<strong>on</strong>,specialised social services and employment services were transferredto the <strong>municipal</strong>ities. As a result, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities have becomestr<strong>on</strong>ger players in the public sector. It has also been argued thatdemocratic decisi<strong>on</strong>-making has strengthened as a result of the newdivisi<strong>on</strong> of tasks. However, according to Blom-Hansen, the latest7


Introducti<strong>on</strong>research evidence suggests that the Danish amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s have notimproved <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy.1.4 Municipal mergers in a metropolitan areaThe fourth chapter of the book, written by Enid Slack and RichardBird, focuses <strong>on</strong> metropolitan governance and <strong>municipal</strong> mergers. Theauthors discuss the merits and drawbacks of alternative metropolitangovernance models based <strong>on</strong> each model’s ability to fulfil importanttargets such as efficiency, accountability, ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale,reducti<strong>on</strong> of negative externalities, and the capacity to deliver andcoordinate services. In particular, the authors discuss the pros andc<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>municipal</strong> mergers compared to the main alternatives such astwo-tier models, voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> and special purpose districts.Although emphasising that the answers are highly c<strong>on</strong>text-specific,and the policy choices are difficult, they do find that the best way tosecure effective governance in a metropolitan regi<strong>on</strong> is either through<strong>on</strong>e-tier (<strong>municipal</strong> mergers) or two-tier models.According to the authors, the main strength of <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>is that it results in <strong>on</strong>e political body that makes taxing and spendingdecisi<strong>on</strong>s. Amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s can also lead to greater fiscal capacity, and<strong>municipal</strong> services may be funded more fairly because there is a widertax base. Bigger <strong>municipal</strong>ities may be able to achieve ec<strong>on</strong>omies ofscale and internalise externalities. Amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s can also lead tobetter service coordinati<strong>on</strong> and more equitable and efficient serviceprovisi<strong>on</strong>. But Slack and Bird also stress that amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s mayreduce access and accountability since jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s may becometoo large and bureaucratic. Moreover, the ability of <strong>municipal</strong>amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s to achieve significant ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale has beenquesti<strong>on</strong>ed in many empirical studies. One reas<strong>on</strong> for these resultsis that most <strong>municipal</strong> services are labour-intensive, and this maymake it hard to achieve significant ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. The benefitsof amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s are also case-specific: ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale arehard to achieve in regi<strong>on</strong>s with low-density housing that is spreadout and more costly to serve. Many empirical studies c<strong>on</strong>clude that8


Antti Moisiothere may not be many further ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale to achieve <strong>on</strong>ce<strong>municipal</strong>ities are much larger than 20,000–40,000 in populati<strong>on</strong>.The cost savings that are obtained from scale ec<strong>on</strong>omies may alsobe more than outweighed by the costs that result, for example, fromwage and service level harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> in the merged <strong>municipal</strong>ity.Finally, the authors note that <strong>municipal</strong> mergers rarely result inboundaries that encompass the entire ec<strong>on</strong>omic regi<strong>on</strong>.Slack and Bird acknowledge that <strong>municipal</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong> is very faradvanced am<strong>on</strong>g Finnish <strong>municipal</strong>ities and that the cooperati<strong>on</strong>applies to important services such as hospital services. At best,<strong>municipal</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong> can achieve ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in servicedelivery and address externalities associated with service provisi<strong>on</strong>.By entering into inter-<strong>municipal</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>municipal</strong>ities canmaintain their spending and taxati<strong>on</strong> aut<strong>on</strong>omy, and, if needed,cooperati<strong>on</strong> can also be easily disbanded. On the other hand,cooperati<strong>on</strong> may become difficult if the member <strong>municipal</strong>ities havevery different objectives. Slack and Bird point out that cooperati<strong>on</strong>involves bargaining and some <strong>municipal</strong>ities may not have much tobargain with. Especially in metropolitan areas, the problems that needto be solved (global competiti<strong>on</strong>, fiscal disparities, sprawl) may beso great that more a permanent instituti<strong>on</strong>al soluti<strong>on</strong> than voluntarycooperati<strong>on</strong> is needed.A two-tier model has many advantages compared with single-tieradministrati<strong>on</strong>s or inter-<strong>municipal</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong> arrangements. In atwo-tier governance model, ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale and scope can beachieved at the upper-tier, whilst the lower tier can provide serviceswhere <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> variati<strong>on</strong> in preferences is important. The two-tier modelcan easily incorporate large areas to internalise externalities andredistribute through tax and spending policies at the upper-tier level.However, Slack and Bird also write that two-tier structures can beless transparent and more c<strong>on</strong>fusing to taxpayers than single-tieradministrati<strong>on</strong>s. At worst, the two-tier model can result in waste andduplicati<strong>on</strong> in the provisi<strong>on</strong> of services.9


Introducti<strong>on</strong>In their article, Slack and Bird use the merger of the Tor<strong>on</strong>tometropolitan area to illustrate the effects of <strong>reform</strong>ing metropolitangovernance. In 1998 the Province of Ontario decided to merge theTor<strong>on</strong>to metropolitan <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the six lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities(including the former City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to) into <strong>on</strong>e single-tier City ofTor<strong>on</strong>to. In other words, the two-tier metropolitan system that hadbeen in place since 1954 was aband<strong>on</strong>ed. The aim of the <strong>reform</strong>was to reduce costs. But, according to the authors, the merger in theTor<strong>on</strong>to area did not prove to be a big success. In their analysis, Slackand Bird find almost no cost savings. On the revenue side, residentialproperty taxes did not change much following the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>.Business property taxes declined following the amalgamati<strong>on</strong> largelyas a result of the amalgamated city’s policy of reducing the tax burden<strong>on</strong> business and the changing provincial rules governing propertytaxes. The positive effects of the <strong>reform</strong>, according to Slack and Bird,include a fairer sharing of the tax base am<strong>on</strong>g the <strong>municipal</strong>ities,harm<strong>on</strong>isati<strong>on</strong> of service levels and increased political weight forTor<strong>on</strong>to in a regi<strong>on</strong>al and nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text.In the last secti<strong>on</strong> of their article, Slack and Bird comment <strong>on</strong> theplans to <strong>reform</strong> Finnish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, especially metropolitangovernance. Although they emphasise that the Helsinki regi<strong>on</strong> differsc<strong>on</strong>siderably from the Tor<strong>on</strong>to metropolitan area, they find it unlikelythat c<strong>on</strong>siderable ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale could be achieved throughamalgamati<strong>on</strong> <strong>reform</strong>s in the Helsinki regi<strong>on</strong>. As for voluntary<strong>municipal</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong>, the authors cast serious doubt <strong>on</strong> the ideathat by cooperating <strong>municipal</strong>ities would be able to develop a joint“regi<strong>on</strong>al” visi<strong>on</strong> to coordinate service delivery, land use planning ortransportati<strong>on</strong>. Therefore, Slack and Bird c<strong>on</strong>clude that despite theproblems associated with the two-tier model, it would still be the bestalternative for <strong>reform</strong> in the Helsinki regi<strong>on</strong>.1.5 Municipal mergers and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>The fifth and last chapter of the book is written by Tuukka Saarimaaand Janne Tukiainen. Their article examines the importance of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>10


Antti Moisiorepresentati<strong>on</strong> in Finnish <strong>municipal</strong>ities, with a special focus <strong>on</strong>voting behaviour in the c<strong>on</strong>text of <strong>municipal</strong> mergers. Citizen-votersmay benefit from having a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representative in the council fora number of reas<strong>on</strong>s. First, if households with similar preferenceshave a tendency to sort into same <strong>municipal</strong>ities or neighborhoods,a councilor living close to a voter is more likely to share thepreferences of the voter in terms of the service-tax bundle providedby the <strong>municipal</strong>ity. The sec<strong>on</strong>d reas<strong>on</strong> why <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> maybe important is related to the comm<strong>on</strong> pool problem. If there areidentifiable (geographic) <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> groups within a <strong>municipal</strong>ity thatbenefit from spending in their area and if the spending is financedglobally by all taxpayers in the <strong>municipal</strong>ity, having a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>representative may be instrumental in receiving the benefits from<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending. Third, if councilors and voters c<strong>on</strong>sume similarservices and dislike travel costs, a councilor living close to a voteris more likely to share the voter’s preferences over the geographiclocati<strong>on</strong> of public services. Furthermore, since house values are tiedto the prevalence and quality of (public) services in the neighborhood,house value becomes an incentive device that may aligncouncilors’ and voters’ preferences. In this case, both the citizenvoterand the councilor want to promote policies that increaseneighborhood quality.The empirical analysis of Saarimaa and Tukiainen is based <strong>on</strong> aunique individual candidate and polling district level data. Usingthis informati<strong>on</strong>, each merged <strong>municipal</strong>ity is decomposed into theoriginal pre-merger <strong>municipal</strong>ities so that the vote distributi<strong>on</strong>s ofcandidates can be traced back to the pre-merger <strong>municipal</strong> level. Theresearchers then perform a difference-in-differences analysis wherethe unit of observati<strong>on</strong> is the pre-merger <strong>municipal</strong>ity and the votingdata comes from electi<strong>on</strong>s before (2004) and after (2008) the seriesof mergers.The authors find that <strong>municipal</strong> mergers lead voters to c<strong>on</strong>centratetheir votes <strong>on</strong> those <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidates that seem to defend thegeographic locati<strong>on</strong> of public services best. This effect is the largerthe farther away the <strong>municipal</strong>ity is from its larger merger partner.11


Introducti<strong>on</strong>However, despite the importance of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>, voters are notwilling to cross party lines in order to guarantee <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>.Based <strong>on</strong> these results, Saarimaa and Tukiainen argue thatpolicymaking should pay special attenti<strong>on</strong> to voters’ preferences overthe locati<strong>on</strong> of public services and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>, especially ifforced mergers of <strong>municipal</strong>ities are planned.12


Antti MoisioReferencesBlöchliger, H. – Vammalle, C. (2012): Reforming Fiscal Relati<strong>on</strong>s and LocalGovernment: Bey<strong>on</strong>d the Zero-Sum Game, OECD Publishing, Paris.Shah, A. (2005): Fiscal Management, World Bank, Public Sector Governance andAccountability Series, Washingt<strong>on</strong>.13


Chapter 2Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>se 1Lars-Erik BorgeJørn RattsøDepartment of Ec<strong>on</strong>omicsNorwegian University of Science and Technology2.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong>The standard theory of fiscal federalism prescribes major fiscaloperati<strong>on</strong>s at the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> level. Given a benevolent plannerat the center, the theory develops arguments for decentralizati<strong>on</strong>.Since the gain of decentralizati<strong>on</strong> relates to the heterogeneity ofpreferences for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods, the main tasks of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> areassumed centralized. The optimal size structure of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>sis determined by the cost c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and heterogeneity of preferencesfor <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods. The expanded case for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sectoradds arguments for the handling of individual redistributive welfareservices (such as schooling and health care) at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level. Thefiscal federalism relevant for the Nordic countries represents animportant role of decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the welfare state, andwe will discuss the challenges that follow.The alternative view of fiscal federalism is more decentralist innature. The advantages of fiscal competiti<strong>on</strong> represent a case fordecentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Brennan and Buchanan (1980) suggesteda competitive federalism where decentralizati<strong>on</strong> is a mechanismto c<strong>on</strong>trol inefficient central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. In this setting, the role1 We appreciate discussi<strong>on</strong>s with Antti Moisio.15


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>seof central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> is less clear. The comprehensive literatureabout ‘Leviathan’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> is not explicit about the sources of<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> failure. Mobility and competiti<strong>on</strong> are relevant in theNordic c<strong>on</strong>text also, but the dominating thinking has c<strong>on</strong>centrated <strong>on</strong>the understanding of the public sector as an administrative system.The new ‘sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong>’ fiscal federalism theory introducespolitical and instituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for the working of fiscalfederalism (Oates, 2005, Boadway and Shah, 2009). This literaturedeals with issues of fiscal discipline and accountability and is ofparticular relevance for the Nordic model with a str<strong>on</strong>g center. Recentcollecti<strong>on</strong>s of country studies by Rodden et al. (2003) and Daffl<strong>on</strong>(2002) discuss the c<strong>on</strong>cern for opportunistic behavior, excessive<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and fiscal imbalance in federalist systems. They formthe background of the “dangers of decentralizati<strong>on</strong>” discussed byPrud’homme (1995).The Nordics struggle with the balancing of integrati<strong>on</strong> into thewelfare state and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> aut<strong>on</strong>omy. The expansi<strong>on</strong> of welfare serviceshas increased the role of decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, but has alsoincreased the involvement of central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Some argue thatthe welfare state aspects have threatened basic values of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> selfrule and democracy. Nordic <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s have <strong>reform</strong>ed their fiscalfederalism to improve the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for the handling of expandedwelfare services and to strengthen <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> accountability. Thebackground and c<strong>on</strong>tent of the <strong>reform</strong> process are discussed in thisarticle.2.2 Fiscal discipline and accountabilityAs menti<strong>on</strong>ed in the introducti<strong>on</strong>, the c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al theory of fiscalfederalism is really a theory about decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> of public goods accommodates preferenceheterogeneity, but must be traded off against the disadvantagesassociated with ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale and externalities. The theorydesigns well-functi<strong>on</strong>ing decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s that can handle16


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsøthe resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities with accountability. The workhorse Musgrave-Oates-Tiebout model (Musgrave, 1959, Oates, 1972, Tiebout, 1956)is based <strong>on</strong> four key assumpti<strong>on</strong>s: Local public goods, benefittaxati<strong>on</strong>, mobility, and no spillovers. The strength of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> publicsector is competiti<strong>on</strong> (Tiebout) and balancing of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> benefits andcosts (Oates’ decentralizati<strong>on</strong> theorem). Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in thisdesign are like Buchanan (1965) clubs established by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>populati<strong>on</strong> to solve comm<strong>on</strong> problems. Benefit taxati<strong>on</strong> assures <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>accountability, and there is no case for central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> financialc<strong>on</strong>trols.The normative c<strong>on</strong>sequences of the standard model are well knownand assign a str<strong>on</strong>g role for the center. The distributi<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>and the stabilizati<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>, using the terminology of Musgrave,must be centralized. In the allocati<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>, public goods shouldbe centralized in areas with str<strong>on</strong>g externalities and ec<strong>on</strong>omies ofscale and homogenous preferences across regi<strong>on</strong>s. The case fordecentralizati<strong>on</strong> is really to realize allocati<strong>on</strong> gains for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> publicgoods. The subsidiarity principle, approved by the EU, argues thatpublic goods should be organized at the lowest level appropriate.The standard recipe assumes fiscal discipline and accountability in<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> units with high degree of aut<strong>on</strong>omy. But in practice all countriesstruggle with the c<strong>on</strong>trol of decentralized spending. It is importantto understand the active involvement of central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.Already the basic model allows for central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grants tointernalize externalities between decentralized units. The early studyby Boadway and Flatters (1982) shows how grants can correct forimperfecti<strong>on</strong>s in mobility due to c<strong>on</strong>gesti<strong>on</strong>. The desire to establishinsurance against shocks also c<strong>on</strong>stitute an argument for grants(Perss<strong>on</strong> and Tabellini, 1996). Even more important in practice areissues of tax design. Benefit taxati<strong>on</strong> for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods is bestachieved by property taxati<strong>on</strong>. But property taxes hardly anywheregenerate revenue above 2–3% of GDP. Other taxes are further awayfrom the principle of benefit taxati<strong>on</strong> and there are few ’good’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>tax bases anyway. The central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> therefore typically addsfunds from broader tax bases like the value added tax and the income17


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>setax. Although central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grants can be based <strong>on</strong> efficiencyc<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s, they imply central funding of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>s and c<strong>on</strong>sequentlyvertical fiscal imbalance.In additi<strong>on</strong>, central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> funding of decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>spending is based <strong>on</strong> distributi<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>cerns. Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s havevarying (private) income levels and their tax bases differ, and grantsare introduced for tax equalizati<strong>on</strong>. In theory equalizati<strong>on</strong> can bearranged at the individual level, but in practice regi<strong>on</strong>al equalizati<strong>on</strong>is made through <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. The desires for equalizati<strong>on</strong>from the center are broader when welfare service spending isdecentralized. Equalizati<strong>on</strong> of spending is designed in complex grantsystems taking into account factors affecting service demand such asthe age compositi<strong>on</strong> of the populati<strong>on</strong> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> cost factors such asthe settlement pattern and populati<strong>on</strong> size.Vertical fiscal imbalance seems hard to avoid. Benefits are enjoyedat the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level, but are at least partly financed from a comm<strong>on</strong> poolof nati<strong>on</strong>al resources. Careaga and Weingast (2000) call such revenuesharing for a “fiscal pact with the devil”. They put the attenti<strong>on</strong> tothe political and instituti<strong>on</strong>al framework of fiscal federalism that cangenerate incentives for good or bad governance. The comm<strong>on</strong> poolproblem implies a spending pressure towards central funds and alsopossibly strategic or opportunistic behavior, and c<strong>on</strong>sequently a biasto overspending. Interestingly, McKinn<strong>on</strong> and Nechyba (1997, p. 55)see more emphasis <strong>on</strong> equity as the major threat, even “the beginningof a slow collapse of the relatively successful US federal system intoa unitary state”.The essence of the comm<strong>on</strong> pool problem within nati<strong>on</strong>s is that theperceived costs of public services at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> or district level are lowerthan the actual costs. The services offered by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sectorsupply benefits to specific geographic areas, here called districts. Whilethe benefits are c<strong>on</strong>centrated, the financing is shared through central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxati<strong>on</strong> distributed out as grants. The benefits are fullyinternalized in each district, but these c<strong>on</strong>tribute <strong>on</strong>ly to a share of thefinancing. The districts c<strong>on</strong>sequently impose negative externalities <strong>on</strong>18


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsøeach other. This understanding of overspending bias was suggestedby Tullock (1959) and developed by Buchanan and Tullock (1962)and Weingast, Shepsle and Johnsen (1981) in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the USC<strong>on</strong>gress. In the extreme case, each district’s spending is financed outof a comm<strong>on</strong> pool of nati<strong>on</strong>al tax revenues. As shown by Perss<strong>on</strong> andTabellini (1999, secti<strong>on</strong> 9), the comm<strong>on</strong> pool problem in this case canbe described as the situati<strong>on</strong> where each district sets the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> serviceproducti<strong>on</strong> with the tax rate determined residually.The sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> fiscal federalism literature addresses designof political and fiscal instituti<strong>on</strong>s to internalize these externalities andto c<strong>on</strong>trol overspending. The starting point is the universalism theoryof collective behavior developed by Weingast (1979) assuming thatall districts are represented in a nati<strong>on</strong>al legislature. Under a “normof universalism” all representatives are members of the winningcoaliti<strong>on</strong>. The norm is a result of a fundamental uncertainty facing therepresentatives. Will they be in, or out, of the winning coaliti<strong>on</strong>? Theuncertainty is removed under the norm of universalism. Comparedto a winning coaliti<strong>on</strong> that includes less than all representatives, thebenefit to each member of the coaliti<strong>on</strong> is reduced. However, a smallbut certain benefit may be preferred to a larger but uncertain benefit.Weingast et al. (1981) have not developed a full political equilibrium,and more recent theoretical research has addressed the decisi<strong>on</strong>making within legislature when projects with c<strong>on</strong>centrated benefitsare financed by universal taxati<strong>on</strong> [see Chari and Cole (1995)and Perss<strong>on</strong> and Tabellini (1999)]. In the setting of a multi-partyparliamentary system with proporti<strong>on</strong>al representati<strong>on</strong> from districts,the parties will to some extent internalize the costs of decentralizedspending, thereby limiting universalistic behavior and the negativec<strong>on</strong>sequences of centralized financing and vertical fiscal imbalances.But when the parties have their str<strong>on</strong>gholds in different regi<strong>on</strong>sand have different marginal districts, they will not agree aboutthe geographical distributi<strong>on</strong> of funds. In this setting the partycompositi<strong>on</strong> of the parliament is the crucial determinant of politicalstrength to hold back the spending pressure.19


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>seThe comm<strong>on</strong> pool challenge to fiscal discipline is not limited tosituati<strong>on</strong>s with serious vertical fiscal imbalance. The key point is thatindiscipline results when the center holds a soft budget c<strong>on</strong>strainttowards the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>s and hands out (marginal) funds with discreti<strong>on</strong>. Theexcess spending bias c<strong>on</strong>sequently is the result of lack of commitmentto a hard budget c<strong>on</strong>straint. The design of fiscal resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities, theworking of the political system, and the commitment problems allinfluence the degree of internalizati<strong>on</strong>. The less<strong>on</strong>s made about theworking of different political systems and fiscal restricti<strong>on</strong>s in thisrespect offer some guidelines for the design of fiscal instituti<strong>on</strong>s.The understanding above is first and for all relevant for the c<strong>on</strong>trol andregulati<strong>on</strong> of decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. But it is also relevant for thediscussi<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> size structure. The standard approachbalances heterogeneity of preferences and costs of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goodsto define optimal size of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. The challenges of fiscaldiscipline and accountability introduce new factors in the equati<strong>on</strong>.The <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> units should have financial strength based <strong>on</strong> own revenuesto take ec<strong>on</strong>omic resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for the costs and risks associatedwith service producti<strong>on</strong>. It is easier for central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s to holdhard budget c<strong>on</strong>straints when decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trollarge own revenue bases. The resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for welfare services alsorequires capacity and competence to operate advanced technologyand knowledge and to develop the services. Presumably the optimalsize of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> units is larger in this setting.2.3 Empirical evidence of comm<strong>on</strong> pool and verticalimbalanceThe understanding of the comm<strong>on</strong> pool problem in fiscal systems hasbeen developed and investigated empirically in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the USC<strong>on</strong>gress. Inman (1988) and Inman and Fitts (1990), analyzing federalgrants and federal spending in the US, represent the first ec<strong>on</strong>ometricstudies of the universalistic model. They show the importance ofmajority-rule leadership in C<strong>on</strong>gress and a str<strong>on</strong>g president to set the20


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsøagenda and coordinate the nati<strong>on</strong>al policy. This is the broad less<strong>on</strong>for political design. An agenda-setter is needed to overcome thegeographical interests.The available analyses relevant for European countries and politicalsystems have mostly taken a broader view of the fiscal challenge.Perotti and K<strong>on</strong>topoulos (2002) address fragmented fiscal policy inOECD countries and analyze the political side of the comm<strong>on</strong> poolproblem as a relati<strong>on</strong>ship between the number of decisi<strong>on</strong> makersand the size of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The size fragmentati<strong>on</strong> is measured asnumber of parties in the ruling coaliti<strong>on</strong> and number of spendingministries. They follow an extensive empirical literature of the effectsof political structure and political fragmentati<strong>on</strong> started up by Roubiniand Sachs (1989). The broad c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> from this literature at thecountry level is that political fragmentati<strong>on</strong> tends to lead to larger<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> size and that the comm<strong>on</strong> pool problem is an importantbackground factor. Hallerberg and Hagen (1999) extend the analysisto electoral instituti<strong>on</strong>s, which is a background determinant of politicalfragmentati<strong>on</strong>.The relati<strong>on</strong>ship between decentralizati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> size has been investigated in light of the hypothesis thatcompetiti<strong>on</strong> leads to smaller <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> (Brennan and Buchanan,1980). The empirical studies following Oates (1985) are not ableto establish that decentralizati<strong>on</strong> holds back <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> size.Kirchgässner (2002) surveys the arguments and estimates. Thehypothesis that decentralizati<strong>on</strong> implies comm<strong>on</strong> pool problems andgenerates larger <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> has been studied for Latin-Americancountries in a research project at the Inter-American DevelopmentBank. The project emphasizes vertical fiscal imbalance and otheraspects of inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al relati<strong>on</strong>s that may give rise to softbudget c<strong>on</strong>straints. Stein (1999) c<strong>on</strong>cludes that decentralizati<strong>on</strong>tends to produce larger <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, and in particular when verticalfiscal imbalance is high, central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grants are discreti<strong>on</strong>al,and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowing aut<strong>on</strong>omy is large. Interestingly, vertical fiscalimbalance here is a level effect and not limited to marginal funds.21


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>seExpansi<strong>on</strong> of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sector over time has been studied inthe same perspective. Borge and Rattsø (2002) analyze the fiscalfederalism design in Norway in an ec<strong>on</strong>ometric analysis of growth of<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public spending during 1880–1990. The benefits of decentralized<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending are c<strong>on</strong>centrated to each <strong>municipal</strong>ity and county,while the costs to a large extent are carried by general taxati<strong>on</strong> anddistributed as central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grants. The party fragmentati<strong>on</strong> of theparliament is the main determinant of the political strength to internalizecosts and thereby c<strong>on</strong>tribute to a socially efficient allocati<strong>on</strong> in thissystem. Party fragmentati<strong>on</strong> of parliament is measured by a Herfindahlindex, and has a significant impact <strong>on</strong> decentralized spending growth.Two other indicators of political strength, capturing type and durati<strong>on</strong>of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, are shown to have similar effects. Internalizati<strong>on</strong> ofcosts seems to be a serious challenge to the nati<strong>on</strong>al political systemunder vertical fiscal imbalance. The asymmetry between decentralizedspending and centralized financing c<strong>on</strong>tributes to public sector growth.Experiences at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> level offer broader databases forempirical testing. Direct tests of the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between districtingand <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending are hard to do, since most politicalsystems are more complex. Petterss<strong>on</strong>-Lidbom (2012) has shownthat the size of the legislature affects the size of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. In hisstudy of Swedish <strong>municipal</strong>ities a higher number of legislators isassociated with smaller size of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. City councils across UScity <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s come closer to theory and are analyzed by Baqir(1999). The size of the city councils is determined by their districting,and redistricting is not a very frequent event. The analysis of UScities c<strong>on</strong>firms that larger city councils are associated with larger<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditures per capita. The effects of districting areestimated in a demand model of city <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending, and themain result seems to be robust to alternative ec<strong>on</strong>ometric approachesand alternative measures of spending. The quantative effect is ofec<strong>on</strong>omic interest, since adding <strong>on</strong>e district <strong>on</strong> average raises percapita spending by 3%.Outside the US district representati<strong>on</strong>, empirical measures of thecomm<strong>on</strong> pool problem is harder to find. An analysis of high school22


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsøspending by county <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in Norway gives some indirectevidence (Falch and Rattsø, 1999). The high schools offer benefits toeach <strong>municipal</strong>ity such as employment and higher <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax revenues.Also the presence of a high school reduces student commuting andmay increase enrollment. It follows that <strong>municipal</strong>ities can obtainbenefits from a comm<strong>on</strong> pool when the costs are shared within thecounty. In this study, the average populati<strong>on</strong> size of the <strong>municipal</strong>ity isa measure of the comm<strong>on</strong> pool effect. Many small <strong>municipal</strong>ities areassumed to have the same effect as many districts. School spending isdisaggregated to separate between the sources of variati<strong>on</strong> in teacherstudentratio, n<strong>on</strong>-wage spending per student, and student enrollment.In the estimated demand model of county level school spending,the average size of the <strong>municipal</strong>ity has a clear impact. Resourceuse per student goes up when the average populati<strong>on</strong> size of the<strong>municipal</strong>ities is reduced. The <strong>municipal</strong>ities seem to be successful ininfluencing the number and the locati<strong>on</strong> of high schools determinedby the counties. The teacher-student ratio increases because smallerschools mean smaller classes, and n<strong>on</strong>-wage spending increasesbecause more schools mean more administrati<strong>on</strong> and maintenanceper student.The database <strong>on</strong> high school spending allows simultaneous analysisof the comm<strong>on</strong> pool effect and political instituti<strong>on</strong>s. While averagesize of <strong>municipal</strong>ities measure spending pressure, political strengthaffects the ability to hold back the pressure. Political strength ismeasured by type of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> a la Roubini and Sachs (1989),separating between majority and minority and <strong>on</strong>e party versuscoaliti<strong>on</strong>, and by a Herfindahl index of party fragmentati<strong>on</strong> of thecounty councils. Falch and Rattsø (1999) apply interacti<strong>on</strong> termsbetween <strong>municipal</strong>ity size and political strength, and the estimatesshow that spending pressure is most effective in counties withweak political leadership. The effect of <strong>municipal</strong>ity size <strong>on</strong> studentenrollment is str<strong>on</strong>g and depends critically <strong>on</strong> political strength. Inweak county councils, smaller <strong>municipal</strong>ities increase resource useper student at the cost of student enrollment, while str<strong>on</strong>g countycouncils are able to increase student enrollment.23


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>seWe c<strong>on</strong>clude that multiple layers of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> represent achallenge for fiscal discipline. The inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al relati<strong>on</strong>svary across countries with different assignments of resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities,different sources of financing, and different ec<strong>on</strong>omic and politicalaut<strong>on</strong>omies at the levels involved. The empirical literature indicatesthat countries share comm<strong>on</strong> problems of central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trolof decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The instituti<strong>on</strong>al resp<strong>on</strong>ses in particularhave been developed to c<strong>on</strong>trol deficits and debt.2.4 Intertemporal imbalances and deficitsOversized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> can be understood as the result of the staticcomm<strong>on</strong> pool problem discussed above. The associated c<strong>on</strong>cern forstabilizati<strong>on</strong> and deficit bias requires an extensi<strong>on</strong> into dynamics andmobility. The essence of the fiscal federalist model is that householdsand firms can move between jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s. The competiti<strong>on</strong> forhouseholds and firms and the threat of exit are important discipliningdevices <strong>on</strong> fiscal performance.The main worry is fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> as a source of fiscalcrisis. Excessive <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> deficits and debts may generate overall fiscalimbalance and with high social costs. The issues are clearly relevantfor the present day understanding of fiscal balance in the US and inthe Euro area. In our c<strong>on</strong>text, the mobility of households representsan incentive for deficit financing. If <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s borrow tofinance current spending, the costs are shifted to future taxpayers.Households may see this as an attractive financing alternative,because they can move out before the bill is paid. Capitalizati<strong>on</strong> willwork to c<strong>on</strong>straint the mobility mechanism. At best, private creditmarkets will evaluate the creditworthiness of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>sand stop the borrowing spree in due time. The problem here isthe possible mechanisms of soft budget c<strong>on</strong>straint for the central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> can hardly be passive when<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s default and financial markets and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxpayerssuffer. The expectati<strong>on</strong> of central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> bailout will encourage24


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsøfurther <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> deficits and debt. It should be noticed that such deficitsmay appear in complicated ways like pensi<strong>on</strong> underfunding.Inman (2003) clarifies the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for ‘deficit-shifting’ and studiesmore closely the excepti<strong>on</strong>s to the US success of fiscal discipline,notably the recessi<strong>on</strong> in the 1930’s and more recent big city crises(like New York City, Washingt<strong>on</strong> DC, Philadelphia and Miami).He identifies instituti<strong>on</strong>s promoting fiscal discipline, in particularpowerful presidents, c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al balanced budget rules, and fiscaloversight boards. His major c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> is that “this traditi<strong>on</strong> ofrefusing to provide significant nati<strong>on</strong>al fiscal relief to <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s indistress c<strong>on</strong>tinues to this day”.The deficit bias of decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> inherent in fiscalfederalism necessitates instituti<strong>on</strong>al restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> behaviorto avoid moral hazard. All countries with decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>have put restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, although in various forms andstrength. Balanced budget rules and limits to borrowing are the twomain instruments of c<strong>on</strong>trol. Recent country studies of c<strong>on</strong>straints andtheir performance are offered by Ter-Minassian (1997) and Daffl<strong>on</strong>(2002). Country studies of bailout mechanisms and experiences arecollected in Fernandez-Arias et al. (2003) and Rodden et al. (2003). Inprinciple, fiscal discipline can be taken care of by market c<strong>on</strong>straints,political c<strong>on</strong>straints or administrative c<strong>on</strong>straints. Private credit andproperty markets can discipline <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s <strong>on</strong>ly when the<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>s have full ec<strong>on</strong>omic aut<strong>on</strong>omy and provide the credit marketwith full informati<strong>on</strong> about their ec<strong>on</strong>omic situati<strong>on</strong>. US states andCanadian provinces seem to be the <strong>on</strong>ly decentralized units wheremarket discipline plays an important part. We are then left to thecombinati<strong>on</strong> of political structure and administrative regulati<strong>on</strong>s tosecure discipline in more integrated public sectors.Most of the empirical literature analyzes aggregate measuresof fiscal imbalance in cross-country studies. Alesina and Perotti(1995) summarize the fiscal c<strong>on</strong>sequences of a variety of aspectsof the political system in OECD countries. The main c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> isthat political fragmentati<strong>on</strong> is associated with fiscal deficits. Weak25


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>se<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s lead to deficits as well as <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> oversize becausethey are unable to internalize costs. The effects of inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>alfiscal relati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> fiscal balance are less clear. Mello (2000) relatesboth central and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal balance to measures oftax aut<strong>on</strong>omy and vertical fiscal imbalance in a cross-countrystudy. Local tax aut<strong>on</strong>omy (<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxes high share of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> revenue)tend to worsen fiscal positi<strong>on</strong>s both for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>s and the central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of vertical imbalance (grantshigh share of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> revenue) are mixed. Interestingly, restricti<strong>on</strong>scan be understood as the result of the inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al relati<strong>on</strong>s.V<strong>on</strong> Hagen and Eichengreen (1996) test the relati<strong>on</strong>ship betweenvertical fiscal imbalance and borrowing restricti<strong>on</strong>s in a dataset of 45countries. They find ec<strong>on</strong>ometric evidence that centralized financingis associated with borrowing c<strong>on</strong>trols. They also find that countrieswith borrowing restricti<strong>on</strong>s have higher <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> debt. Theunderstanding is that the fiscal pressure against the center is higherwhen the center c<strong>on</strong>trols the funds.Studies of fiscal restricti<strong>on</strong>s at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> level are hard todo since most countries have comm<strong>on</strong> rules for all <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.There is no variati<strong>on</strong> in regulati<strong>on</strong>s to take advantage from. TheEuropean case studies edited by Daffl<strong>on</strong> (2002) show that countriesapply different forms of restricti<strong>on</strong>s to budget balance and borrowing.All allow for administrative discreti<strong>on</strong> at the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>level, and all struggle with <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> authorities attempting to get aroundthe restricti<strong>on</strong>s (typically off-budget activities). Restricti<strong>on</strong>s seem towork although they are imperfect. The episodes of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal crisisexperienced, notably in Italy and Spain in the late 1970s, motivatedan overhaul of the fiscal c<strong>on</strong>trols. Central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> interventi<strong>on</strong>sand bailouts were followed by instituti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>reform</strong>s to avoid futurerepetiti<strong>on</strong>s. Many c<strong>on</strong>tributors to Daffl<strong>on</strong>’s volume report that theEMU process has been helpful in arranging sustainable balances.More extensive ec<strong>on</strong>ometric studies of the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of budgetbalance requirements and borrowing limitati<strong>on</strong>s are made for the USstates. The US states with their relative homogeneity and instituti<strong>on</strong>alvariati<strong>on</strong> offer an attractive database for the investigati<strong>on</strong> of fiscal26


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsørestricti<strong>on</strong>s. The states generally have balanced budget requirementsand limitati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> debt, but in different forms. V<strong>on</strong> Hagen (1991) didan innovative study of how these rules affect state indebtness. Themotivati<strong>on</strong> for his study was the discussi<strong>on</strong> about European m<strong>on</strong>etaryintegrati<strong>on</strong> and the use of fiscal restraint. The US case represents anopportunity to investigate how fiscal restraints in a m<strong>on</strong>etary uni<strong>on</strong>are functi<strong>on</strong>ing. His main c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> is that fiscal restraints ‘do littleto reduce the likelihood of extreme outcomes in fiscal performance’and thus that they cannot be expected to be effective in a Europeanm<strong>on</strong>etary uni<strong>on</strong>.Poterba (1997) summarizes the many studies available about US statesand classifies three main types of regulati<strong>on</strong>s: Required submissi<strong>on</strong>of a balanced budget; required legislative decisi<strong>on</strong> of a balancedbudget allowing for actual deficits; combining a balanced budgetfrom the legislature with a prohibiti<strong>on</strong> to carry forward the deficit.The empirical analyses apply an index of the stringency of the state‘sbalanced budget requirements. Most c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s estimate broadmodels of ec<strong>on</strong>omic and political variables affecting spending andrevenue behaviour. The analysts agree that the most restrictive fiscallimits do reduce the state indebtness and also reduce the borrowingcosts for a given deficit. The less<strong>on</strong>s above indicate that nati<strong>on</strong>alrestricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>ly work when they are part of a well-functi<strong>on</strong>ing androbust political decisi<strong>on</strong> making system.2.5 The Nordic model of administrative federalismThe Nordic countries have developed a model of fiscal federalismcharacterised by <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for welfare services, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxfinancing through an income tax, and extensive equalizati<strong>on</strong> systems.Overview and discussi<strong>on</strong> are offered in Rattsø (1998).The background for the development of a Nordic model is the buildingof the welfare state after World War II. Key elements in the buildingof the welfare state were expansi<strong>on</strong> of educati<strong>on</strong>, health care, andsocial services and with the same service standards throughout the27


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>secountry. Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s were given resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for provisi<strong>on</strong>of most welfare services.The assigned role of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in welfare services wasnot grounded in the theory of fiscal federalism emphasizingheterogeneous demand for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods. It was ratherunderstood as administrative delegati<strong>on</strong> from an overburdened centralstate. Compared to central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> agencies, provisi<strong>on</strong> through<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s were c<strong>on</strong>sidered to have advantages in terms ofefficiency and democratic c<strong>on</strong>trol. The efficiency argument was tosome extent related to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>izati<strong>on</strong> of instituti<strong>on</strong>s and the importanceof welfare services for community development. The Nordic modelc<strong>on</strong>sequently has been named as administrative federalism ratherthan fiscal federalism. In the c<strong>on</strong>text of Brueckner’s (2009) theory ofdecentralizati<strong>on</strong> it can be called partial decentralizati<strong>on</strong>.The choice of using the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in the building ofthe welfare state had important implicati<strong>on</strong>s for the design ofinter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al relati<strong>on</strong>s. First, the expansi<strong>on</strong> of welfare serviceswas accompanied by an increase in central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grants. Sec<strong>on</strong>d,tax and spending needs equalizati<strong>on</strong> became more important with theincreased resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for welfare services. Third, legal regulati<strong>on</strong>and earmarking were used to achieve the detailed objectives of eachservice. The increased central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trol and involvementled to less <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> aut<strong>on</strong>omy by increasing the dependence <strong>on</strong> grantfinancing and reducing the importance of tax financing (increasedvertical fiscal imbalances), and by reducing <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> discreti<strong>on</strong> in theallocati<strong>on</strong> of resources across services.There was a growing c<strong>on</strong>cern that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> structure wasnot well suited for the new resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>swere too small to exploit ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale and to develop attractiveenvir<strong>on</strong>ments for highly skilled workers. Nati<strong>on</strong>al amalgamati<strong>on</strong><strong>reform</strong>s were carried out in Sweden, Norway, and Denmark.Sweden led the way by a <strong>reform</strong> in 1952 that reduced the numberof <strong>municipal</strong>ities from nearly 2,500 to just above 1,000 (Dahlberg2010). During the period 1962–74 the number of <strong>municipal</strong>ities was28


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsøfurther reduced to 278. In Norway an amalgamati<strong>on</strong> <strong>reform</strong> wascarried out in the early 1960s, reducing the number of <strong>municipal</strong>itiesfrom nearly 750 to around 450 (Borge 2010). In Denmark more than1,000 parish <strong>municipal</strong>ities and 80 towns were merged into 275<strong>municipal</strong>ities in 1970 (Blom-Hansen 2010). Finland is the <strong>on</strong>lyNordic country without a nati<strong>on</strong>al merger <strong>reform</strong>. However, thenumber of <strong>municipal</strong>ities was reduced from nearly 560 in 1945 to460 in 1990 through voluntary mergers.The rising level of nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>trol was also of c<strong>on</strong>cern. Thismotivated <strong>reform</strong>s to promote <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> accountability,and efficiency by giving <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s more discreti<strong>on</strong> inthe allocati<strong>on</strong> of resources between service sectors. The <strong>reform</strong>sattempted to reduce mandating and regulati<strong>on</strong> in general and in grantsystems earmarked grants were replaced by general grants based<strong>on</strong> objective criteria. The movement to general purpose grants, alsocalled block grants, was gradually introduced in Denmark in the1970s. Later a block grant system was implemented in Norway in1986 and in Finland and Sweden in 1993.The Nordic model is best understood as a mixed model that attemptsat combining <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy with an agency role in welfare services.However, the extent of nati<strong>on</strong>al regulati<strong>on</strong>s varies somewhat acrossthe countries. In terms of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax financing and tax discreti<strong>on</strong>Norway stands out as the least decentralized country. Local taxesamount to around 40% of revenues and in practice there is littletax discreti<strong>on</strong>. Formally the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s can choose tax rateswithin an interval, but since 1980 each and every <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>has used the maximum rate in income and wealth taxati<strong>on</strong>. Inpractice tax discreti<strong>on</strong> is limited to the property tax. The propertytax is a voluntary tax where the tax rate varies across <strong>municipal</strong>ities.They can also decide whether to tax property or not and the type ofproperty to be taxed. However, the property tax <strong>on</strong>ly amounts for5–10% of <strong>municipal</strong> tax revenues. In the other Nordic countries thereis less central regulati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax rates. In Denmark, Finland, andSweden the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s do not impose maximum tax rates inthe income tax, and there is c<strong>on</strong>siderable variati<strong>on</strong> in tax rates across29


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>se<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. However, both in Denmark and Sweden thecentral <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> has temporarily taken acti<strong>on</strong>s to avoid <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxincreases. Sweden had a tax freeze in the early 1990s and in Denmarkthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax level has been a key topic in the annual negotiati<strong>on</strong>sbetween the Danish central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s and Local GovernmentDenmark. Blom-Hansen (2012) argues that <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax discreti<strong>on</strong> inDenmark is de facto abolished after the <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> of 2007.The temporary adjustment rules certainly reduced the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> discreti<strong>on</strong>,and it will be interesting to observe how the tax setting will evolveover time in the new system.There is also c<strong>on</strong>siderable variati<strong>on</strong> across the Nordic countrieswhen it comes to handling fiscal discipline by balanced budget rulesand limitati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> borrowing. In this dimensi<strong>on</strong> Denmark has thestrictest regulati<strong>on</strong>s. In general <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> borrowing is forbidden, butwith permanent exempti<strong>on</strong>s for investments in certain areas such aspublic utilities. Norway has a balanced-budget-rule where the mainrequirement is operati<strong>on</strong>al budget balance. In the budget, currentrevenues must cover current expenditures, interest repayments, andregular instalments of debt repayment. Actual deficits are allowedto be carried over, but as main rule they must be “repaid” withintwo years. If a deficit is not “repaid” within two years, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> is listed in a register (ROBEK) and will be subject tobudget and borrowing c<strong>on</strong>trol. Similar BBRs are in place in Finlandand Sweden, but with no sancti<strong>on</strong>s for violating the BBR.It is tempting to speculate whether there is a relati<strong>on</strong>ship between<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax discreti<strong>on</strong> and fiscal rules, at least when comparing Norwayto Finland and Sweden. More tax discreti<strong>on</strong> in Sweden and Finlandmay reduce the need for tight m<strong>on</strong>itoring of BBRs as the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s have an instrument to raise revenues in times of fiscaldistress. In Norway tighter regulati<strong>on</strong> of the BBR may be necessary toavoid large fiscal crisis where the <strong>on</strong>ly way out is central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>bail-out.To sum up, we think the central regulati<strong>on</strong>s of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s inthe Nordic countries first are foremost must be understood <strong>on</strong> the30


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsøbackground of decentralized resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for welfare services. Taxand expenditure needs equalizati<strong>on</strong>, substantial grant financing, anddetailed regulati<strong>on</strong> of the services are necessary to achieve equalaccess to welfare services. Moreover, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sector makesup a large part of the total ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Nati<strong>on</strong>al regulati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>taxes are to some extent necessary to c<strong>on</strong>trol the overall tax level andbalanced-budget-rules are in place to avoid bail-outs and to c<strong>on</strong>trolthe overall fiscal balance of the public sector.2.6 Fiscal competiti<strong>on</strong> in the Nordic countriesThe literature <strong>on</strong> fiscal federalism emphasizes competiti<strong>on</strong> between<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s as an important disciplinary device. However,competiti<strong>on</strong> has not played an important role in the Nordic modelas the main disciplinary devices are the design of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> politicalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s and central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> regulati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>trol. Ifanything, competiti<strong>on</strong> is seen as a threat to the Nordic model.Söderström (1998) argues that a competiti<strong>on</strong> problem arises when<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are financed by income tax. With a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> incometax communities with wealthy inhabitants will be able to providegood services even with low tax rates. A threat for these wealthycommunities is inmigrati<strong>on</strong> of poor individuals that will erode the taxbase and the good services. C<strong>on</strong>sequently, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s mayengage in competiti<strong>on</strong> to avoid inmigrati<strong>on</strong> of poor people. From anati<strong>on</strong>al perspective this competiti<strong>on</strong> is largely unproductive since thepoor have to reside somewhere. Söderström (1998) makes the pointthat the competiti<strong>on</strong> problem is solved by extensive tax equalizati<strong>on</strong>.In the last decade a growing empirical literature has focused <strong>on</strong> fiscalinteracti<strong>on</strong>s or competiti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. This literatureinvestigates whether the fiscal decisi<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> isaffected by the fiscal decisi<strong>on</strong>s of its neighbours. Several studies fromthe Nordic countries have appeared, analysing tax welfare benefits,tax setting, and efficiency.31


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>seWelfare competiti<strong>on</strong> is analysed by Fiva and Rattsø (2006) andDahlberg and Edmark (2008) using Norwegian and Swedish datarespectively. The two studies analyse welfare benefits to individualsand households not captured by the nati<strong>on</strong>al social insurance systems.Welfare benefit is a transfer program administered at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> level. A key issue is whether there is strategic interacti<strong>on</strong>am<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in the setting of benefit levels. Do <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s react <strong>on</strong> the welfare benefit levels in neighbouringjurisdicti<strong>on</strong> when setting their own benefit levels? Dahlberg andEdmark (2008) find str<strong>on</strong>g evidence of a positive reacti<strong>on</strong>. A<strong>municipal</strong>ity decreases its benefit level by around SEK 40 when theneighbouring <strong>municipal</strong>ities decrease their benefit level by SEK 100.Fiva and Rattsø (2006) document similar effects for Norway.As discussed in the previous secti<strong>on</strong>, the property tax is a voluntarytax for Norwegian <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Fiva and Rattsø (2007) analysewhether fiscal interacti<strong>on</strong>s are important for the discrete decisi<strong>on</strong> tohave property tax. They find that the probability of having a propertytax increases significantly if the neighbouring jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s also usethe property tax. Edmark and Ågren (2008) perform a similar analysis<strong>on</strong> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> income tax in Sweden. As Fiva and Rattsø, they documentpositive spatial interacti<strong>on</strong>s. An average cut of 1 percentage points inneighbouring jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s is correlated with a decrease of about 0.74percentage points in own taxes.A recent Finnish study by Lyytikäinen (2012) uses a clever strategyto identify spatial interacti<strong>on</strong>s in property taxati<strong>on</strong>. In Finland the<strong>municipal</strong>ities can choose property tax rates within an intervaland in 2000 the lower bounds of the intervals were increased. Asa c<strong>on</strong>sequence, many <strong>municipal</strong>ities were forced to increase theirtax rates. When the forced increase in the tax rates of neighbouring<strong>municipal</strong>ities are used as instruments, there is no evidence ofspatial interacti<strong>on</strong> in property tax rates. However, when the standardestimati<strong>on</strong> methods are applied, positive spatial interacti<strong>on</strong>s cannotbe rejected. This suggests that the standard methods may have atendency to overestimate the degree of interdependence in tax rates.32


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn RattsøA possible interpretati<strong>on</strong> of spatial interacti<strong>on</strong>s in tax setting is thatvoters evaluate incumbents by comparing the performance of theirown <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> with the performance of the neighbours.Good performance relatively to the neighbours acts as a signal ofa competent incumbent. Revelli and Tovmo (2007) represent aninteresting twist by analysing spatial interacti<strong>on</strong>s in performance.They utilize an efficiency indicator that is calculated and publishedannually by a <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> commissi<strong>on</strong> set up to m<strong>on</strong>itor <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>public finances in Norway. It appears that the degree of efficiency ispositively correlated across neighbours. Moreover, when exploitingsurvey informati<strong>on</strong> it comes out that significant spatial correlati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong>ly occurs for those <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s that compare their ownservice provisi<strong>on</strong> to those in nearby communities.The above menti<strong>on</strong>ed studies provide clear evidence of spatialinteracti<strong>on</strong>s and competiti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. But is thiscompetiti<strong>on</strong> for good or for bad? In general there are two competingtheoretical frameworks; mobility of households or tax bases or yardstickcompetiti<strong>on</strong>. The typical predicti<strong>on</strong> from the former framework is thatcompetiti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s leads to a race-to-the-bottom,either in welfare benefit levels or tax rates. Yardstick competiti<strong>on</strong>(or performance comparis<strong>on</strong> as discussed above) is seen as a moreproductive type of competiti<strong>on</strong> that may improve policy outcomes.The studies of welfare competiti<strong>on</strong> are probably best understood ascompetiti<strong>on</strong> to avoid inmigrati<strong>on</strong> of welfare recipients and therebyevidence of a race-to-the-bottom. However, Fiva and Rattsø (2006)point out that the spatial interacti<strong>on</strong>s do not necessarily imply toolow benefit levels, since the grant financing of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>smay generate overall excessive spending. At the other end, spatialcorrelati<strong>on</strong> in efficiency as documented by Revelli and Tovmo(2007) is best understood as productive yardstick competiti<strong>on</strong>. Theinterpretati<strong>on</strong> of the tax interacti<strong>on</strong>s is less clear. Edmark and Ågren(2008) find some weak evidence of unproductive tax competiti<strong>on</strong>,while Fiva and Rattsø (2007) argue that their results should beunderstood as evidence as yardstick competiti<strong>on</strong> since the propertytax base is relatively immobile. Lyytikäinen (2012) acknowledges33


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>sethat his identify strategy may not be very relevant for detectingyardstick competiti<strong>on</strong>.2.7 The future of the Nordic modelThe <strong>on</strong>going <strong>reform</strong> process since the 1980s has mainly dealt with thec<strong>on</strong>trol of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, partly in terms of reduced regulati<strong>on</strong>and mandating and c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> of grants, and partly as a morerobust regulatory system related to deficits and debt. More recently<strong>municipal</strong> mergers and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> structure have returned tothe policy agenda. Denmark implemented a major <strong>reform</strong> in 2007where the previous 271 <strong>municipal</strong>ities were merged into 98 new large<strong>municipal</strong>ities and the 14 counties were merged into 5 new regi<strong>on</strong>s.The other countries have a heated discussi<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>structure, but the structure has not changed much the last decades.A possible excepti<strong>on</strong> is Finland where the number of <strong>municipal</strong>itiesis significantly reduced through voluntary mergers the recent years.The <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> structure cannot be determined independentlyof the tasks assigned to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. This co-determinati<strong>on</strong>of structure and tasks was very explicit in the recent Danish <strong>reform</strong>.Al<strong>on</strong>g with the amalgamati<strong>on</strong> <strong>reform</strong> a number of functi<strong>on</strong>s weretransferred from the old counties to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities. The mostimportant functi<strong>on</strong>s were specialized social services and selectedhealth care services. Later, in 2009, the employment policy wasunified and placed with the <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Another example ofthe close link between structure and tasks is the hospital <strong>reform</strong>in Norway. The hospitals had “grown out” of the counties due toincreased specializati<strong>on</strong>. When the structure did not adapt to changingc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, the final outcome was a nati<strong>on</strong>al take-over.The future of the Nordic model of federalism is closely linked tothe future organizati<strong>on</strong> of the welfare services, and in our view twoalternatives stand out. The first alternative is based <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tinued, andpossibly strengthened, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for welfareservices (a renewed model of administrative federalism), while the34


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn Rattsøother is based <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s c<strong>on</strong>centrating <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services(a Nordic model of fiscal federalism).The first alternative can be seen as a c<strong>on</strong>tinuati<strong>on</strong> of the currentNordic model of administrative federalism. However, it is necessaryto acknowledge that the welfare services, and in particular the socialservices, have become more specialized and require more competentpers<strong>on</strong>nel. Moreover, better communicati<strong>on</strong>s has led to drasticreducti<strong>on</strong> in travelling time. These developments call for a new roundof <strong>municipal</strong> mergers to exploit ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale and to build solidgroups of specialists. The <strong>municipal</strong>ities will then be up to the taskof maintaining existing functi<strong>on</strong>s and take <strong>on</strong> new <strong>on</strong>es. Denmark isthe role model in this respect, and the other countries can follow theDanish model. A nati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>reform</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>municipal</strong> mergers is required,especially in Norway and Finland.A renewed model of administrative federalism has severaladvantages. First, larger and str<strong>on</strong>ger <strong>municipal</strong>ities facilitatec<strong>on</strong>tinued decentralizati<strong>on</strong> in the provisi<strong>on</strong> of public services.Sec<strong>on</strong>d, with larger <strong>municipal</strong>ities the variati<strong>on</strong> in tax bases andspending needs will be reduced. The financing can to a larger extentbe based <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxes and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities can be less dependent<strong>on</strong> central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grants. Third, larger <strong>municipal</strong>ities withincreased resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities and more tax financing may strengthen<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy and accountability and increase the political powerof the <strong>municipal</strong> tier.A renewed model of administrative federalism will strengthen thecapacity of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sector to take resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of welfareservices. It is still an open questi<strong>on</strong> how welfare services will beorganized in the future and how the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sector fits in. Inparticular this is discussed regarding the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of hospitals.The model may be combined with <strong>municipal</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong> (as inFinland), regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s with a few functi<strong>on</strong>s (Denmark),or nati<strong>on</strong>al resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for some services currently provided by<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s (Norway). It can also be argued that the new35


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>se<strong>municipal</strong>ities may be “too large” for some services, thereby reducingdecentralizati<strong>on</strong> gains and productive competiti<strong>on</strong>.For hospitals a possible soluti<strong>on</strong> could be to separate the roleof purchaser and the role of producer. The <strong>municipal</strong>ities couldc<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>on</strong> purchasing specialized health service <strong>on</strong> behalf oftheir citizens, while state agencies take care of producti<strong>on</strong>. Thissoluti<strong>on</strong> can be interpreted as an extended versi<strong>on</strong> of recent modelsin Denmark and Norway where the <strong>municipal</strong>ities are co-financingthe use of hospital services. A main argument for these models isto give the <strong>municipal</strong>ities a more coherent resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for healthcare and to provide incentives for preventive acti<strong>on</strong>s. Even if the<strong>municipal</strong>ities are to c<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>on</strong> the purchasing role, there is needfor larger <strong>municipal</strong>ities (in Finland and Norway) in order to limitthe financial risk associated with year-to-year variati<strong>on</strong> in the useof hospital services. However, the most critical issues issues in theevaluati<strong>on</strong> of this model is whether it is possible to be a competentpurchaser of specialized health care without being involved in theproducti<strong>on</strong>.The sec<strong>on</strong>d alternative is to develop a Nordic model of fiscal federalismwhere the burden of welfare services is lifted off the shoulders ofthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sector. Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s can c<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>public goods and other services where nati<strong>on</strong>al goals of equality areless pr<strong>on</strong>ounced. The need for large <strong>municipal</strong>ities is reduced, andin many urban areas break-up of <strong>municipal</strong>ities may be warranted.Larger decentralizati<strong>on</strong> gains and more productive competiti<strong>on</strong> maybe enjoyed for the remaining <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services. Moreover, the need fortax and spending needs equalizati<strong>on</strong> is reduced when redistributivewelfare services are no l<strong>on</strong>ger a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>sibility. The financing canrely more <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxes and the dependence <strong>on</strong> central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>grants will be reduced. Local democracy and accountability willbenefit from having a portfolio of tasks with less central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>regulati<strong>on</strong>, but the scaled down <strong>municipal</strong> tier will have less politicalpower.36


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn RattsøThe main challenge of a Nordic model of fiscal federalism is whatto do with the welfare services that are lifted off the shoulders of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. The natural resp<strong>on</strong>se is that these services must beprovided by the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and a new system of governancemust be set up for each of these services. A positive effect of suchcentralizati<strong>on</strong> is that the emphasis <strong>on</strong> equalizati<strong>on</strong> can be increasedcompared to the present provisi<strong>on</strong> through <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. On thenegative side adjustment to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and preferences will befurther reduced. A central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> organizati<strong>on</strong> of welfare servicesmay create new bureaucracy and inefficiency. The experiences withcentral <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>alizati<strong>on</strong> of hospitals in Norway indicatethat this c<strong>on</strong>cern should be taken into account.Another comm<strong>on</strong> issue in the Nordic countries is the organizati<strong>on</strong>of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in metropolitan areas. The trend is that a largershare of the populati<strong>on</strong> resides in the larger cities and as a c<strong>on</strong>sequencecommuting areas stretch bey<strong>on</strong>d the borders of the central city. It isan argument for a unified metropolitan <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in order to handleservices with substantial spillovers such as infrastructure, roads andpublic transport. As in the general discussi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>municipal</strong> structure,a possible disadvantage is that a unified metropolitan <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>may be “too” large for some services.Overall we expect that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sector in the Nordic countrieswill survive as a large part of the public sector and within a systemof administrative delegati<strong>on</strong> from central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Local<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s will c<strong>on</strong>tinue to be the main service producers of thewelfare state. The c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> holds as l<strong>on</strong>g as broad privatizati<strong>on</strong>of welfare services is out of the questi<strong>on</strong> and central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>is not seen as an efficient organizer of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> schools, care for theelderly and primary health services. In this case mergers between<strong>municipal</strong>ities will be part of the package. Larger <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>swill be necessary to carry welfare services that are getting more andmore advanced and to have the revenue base needed to take the bulkof the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for financing and risk. Fiscal discipline andaccountability will still be challenges that the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>must handle.37


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>seReferencesAlesina, A. – Perotti, R. (1995): The political ec<strong>on</strong>omy of budget deficits, IMF StaffPapers 42, 1–31.Baqir, R. (1999): Districts, spillovers, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> overspending, MimeoDepartment of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, University of California at Berkeley.Bertola, G. – Jimeno, J.F. – Marim<strong>on</strong>, R. – Pissarides, C. (2001): EU welfare systemsand labour markets: Heterogeneous in the past, integrated in the future?, in Bertola,G. – Boeri, T. – Nicoletti, G. (eds.) Welfare and Employment in a United Europe,MIT Press.Besley, T. – Coate, S. (2003): Centralized versus decentralized provisi<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>public goods: A political ec<strong>on</strong>omy approach, Journal of Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 87,2<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>1–2637.Blom-Hansen, J. (2010): Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Denmark, in Moisio, A. (ed.) Localpublic sector in transiti<strong>on</strong>: A Nordic perspective, Government Institute forEc<strong>on</strong>omic Research (<strong>VATT</strong>).Blom-Hansen, J. (2012): The measurement of decentralizati<strong>on</strong>: The challenge ofthe Danish story, forthcoming, in Blöchliger, H. – Kim, J. (eds.) Measuring FiscalDecentralisati<strong>on</strong>, OECD.Boadway, R. – Flatters, F. (1982): Efficiency and equalizati<strong>on</strong> payments in a federalsystem of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>: A synthesis and extensi<strong>on</strong> of recent results, CanadianJournal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 15, <str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>3–633.Boadway, R. – Shah, A. (2009): Fiscal Federalism, Cambridge University Press.Borge, L.-E. (2010): Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Norway, in Moisio, A. (ed.) Local publicsector in transiti<strong>on</strong>: A Nordic perspective, Government Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omicResearch (<strong>VATT</strong>).Borge, L.-E. – Rattsø, J. (2002): Spending growth with vertical fiscal imbalance:Decentralized <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending in Norway 1880-1990, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics andPolitics, 14, 3, 351–373.Brennan, J. – Buchanan, J. (1980): The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundati<strong>on</strong>s of aFiscal C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, Cambridge University Press.Brueckner, J.K. (2009): Partial fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, Regi<strong>on</strong>al Science and UrbanEc<strong>on</strong>omics 39, 23–32.Buchanan, J. (1965): An ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory of clubs, Ec<strong>on</strong>omica 33, 1–14.38


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn RattsøBuchanan, J. – Tullock, G. (1962): The Calculus of C<strong>on</strong>sent, Ann Arbor, Universityof Michigan Press.Careaga, M. – Weingast, B. (2000): The fiscal pact with the devil: A positiveapproach to fiscal federalism, revenue sharing, and good governmance, mimeo,Department of Political Science, Stanford University.Chari, V. – Cole, H. (1995): A c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the theory of pork barrel spending,Research Department Staff Report No. 156, revised versi<strong>on</strong> Federal Reserve Bankof Minneapolis.Dahlberg, M. (2010): Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Sweden, in Moisio, A. (ed.) Local publicsector in transiti<strong>on</strong>: A Nordic perspective, Government Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omicResearch (<strong>VATT</strong>).Dahlberg, M. – Edmark, K. (2008): Is there a “race-to-the-bottom” in the settingof welfare benefit levels? Evidence from a policy interventi<strong>on</strong>, Journal of PublicEc<strong>on</strong>omics 92, 1193–1209.Daffl<strong>on</strong>, B. (2002): Local Public Finance in Europe: Balancing the Budget andC<strong>on</strong>trolling Debt, Edward Elgar.Edmark, K. – Ågren, H. (2008): Identifying strategic interacti<strong>on</strong>s in Swedish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>income tax policies, Journal of Urban Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 63, 849–857.Falch, T. – Rattsø, J. (1999): Local public choice of school spending: disaggregatingthe demand functi<strong>on</strong> for educati<strong>on</strong>al services, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics of Educati<strong>on</strong> Review 18,3<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>–373.Fernandez-Arias, E. – Stein, E. – v<strong>on</strong> Hagen, J. (2003): Subnati<strong>on</strong>al GovernmentBailouts, Inter-American Development Bank.Fiva, J.H. – Rattsø, J. (2006): Welfare competiti<strong>on</strong> in Norway: norms and expenditures,European Journal of Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 22, 202–222.Fiva, J.H. – Rattsø, J. (2007): Local choice of property taxati<strong>on</strong>: evidence fromNorway, Public Choice 132, 457–470.Hallerberg, M. – v<strong>on</strong> Hagen, J. (1999): Electoral instituti<strong>on</strong>s, cabinet negotiati<strong>on</strong>s,and budget deficits, in the European Uni<strong>on</strong>, in Poterba, J. – v<strong>on</strong> Hagen, J. (eds.)Fiscal Instituti<strong>on</strong>s and Fiscal Performance, Chicago University Press and NBER.Inman, R. (1988): Federal assistance and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services in the United States: Theevoluti<strong>on</strong> of a new federalist fiscal order, in Rosen, H. (ed.) Fiscal Federalism:Quantitative Studies, The University of Chicago Press.39


Fiscal federalism: Internati<strong>on</strong>al experiencesand the Nordic resp<strong>on</strong>seInman, R. (2003): Hard and soft budget c<strong>on</strong>straints in the United States, in Rodden,J. – Eskeland, G. – Litvack, J. (eds.) Fiscal Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and the Challenge ofHard Budget C<strong>on</strong>straints, The World Bank.Inman, R.P. – Fitts, M. (1990): Political instituti<strong>on</strong>s and fiscal policy: Evidence fromthe US historical record, Journal of Law, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Organizati<strong>on</strong> 6, SpecialIssue, 79–132.Kirchgässner, G. (2002): The effects of fiscal instituti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> public finance:A survey of the empirical evidence, in Winer, S. – Shibata, H. (eds.) PoliticalEc<strong>on</strong>omy and Public Finance: The Role of Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy in the Theory andPractice of Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omies, Edward Elgar.Lockwood, B. (2002): Distributive politics and the costs of centralisati<strong>on</strong>, Review ofEc<strong>on</strong>omic Studies 69, 313–337.Lyytikäinen, T. (2012): Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s: Evidence from aproperty tax <strong>reform</strong> in Finland, Journal of Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 96, 584–595.McKinn<strong>on</strong>, R. – Nechyba, T. (1997): Competiti<strong>on</strong> in federal systems: The role ofpolitical and financial c<strong>on</strong>straints, in Ferejohn, J. – Weingast, B. (eds.), The NewFederalism: Can the States be Trusted?, Hoover Instituti<strong>on</strong> Press.Mello, L. (2000): Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al fiscal relati<strong>on</strong>s: Across-country analysis, World Development 28, 2, 365–380.Musgrave, R. (1959): The Theory of Public Finance, McGraw Hill.Oates, W. (1972): Fiscal Federalism, Harcourt, Brace and Jovanovic.Oates, W. (1985): Searching for Leviathan: An empirical study, American Ec<strong>on</strong>omicReview 75, 748–757.Oates, W. (2005): Towards a sec<strong>on</strong>d-generati<strong>on</strong> theory of fiscal federalism,Internati<strong>on</strong>al Tax and Public Finance 12, 349–373.Perotti, R. – K<strong>on</strong>topoulos, Y. (2002): Fragmented fiscal policy, Journal of PublicEc<strong>on</strong>omics 86, 191–222.Perss<strong>on</strong>, T. – Tabellini, G. (1996): Federal fiscal c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s: Risk sharing andredistributi<strong>on</strong>, Journal of Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 104, 979–1009.Perss<strong>on</strong>, T. – Tabellini, G. (1999): Political ec<strong>on</strong>omics and public finance, in Auerbach,A. – Feldstein, M. (eds.) Handbook of Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Vol. III.Petterss<strong>on</strong>-Lidbom, P. (2012): Does the size of the legislature affect the size of<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>: Evidence from two natural experiments, Journal of Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics96, 3-4, 269–278.40


Lars-Erik Borge – Jørn RattsøPoterba, J. (1997): Do Budget Rules Work?, in Auerbach, A. (ed.) Fiscal Policy:Less<strong>on</strong>s from Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research, The MIT Press.Prud’homme, R. (1995): The dangers of decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, The World Bank ResearchObserver 10, 2, 201–220.Rattsø, J. (ed.) (1998): Fiscal Federalism and State-Local Finance: The ScandinavianPerspective, Edward Elgar.Revelli, F. – Tovmo, P. (2007): Revealed yardstick competiti<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>efficiency patterns in Norway, Journal of Urban Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 62, 121–134.Rodden, J. – Eskeland, G. – Litvack, J. (eds.) (2003): Fiscal Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and theChallenge of Hard Budget C<strong>on</strong>straints, The World Bank.Roubini, N. – Sachs, J. (1989): Political and ec<strong>on</strong>omic determinants of budget deficitsin the industrial democracies. European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 33, 903–938.Stein, V. (1999): Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> size in Latin America,Journal of Applied Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, II, 2, 357–371.Söderström, L (1998): Fiscal federalism: The Nordic way in Rattsø, J. (Ed.) FiscalFederalism and State-Local Finance: The Scandinavian Perspective, Edward Elgar.Ter-Minassian, T. (ed.) (1997): Fiscal Federalism in Theory and Practice, Internati<strong>on</strong>alM<strong>on</strong>etary Fund.Tiebout, C. (1956): A pure theory of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditures, Journal ofPolitical Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, 64, 416–424.Tullock, G. (1959): Some problems of majority voting, Journal of Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy67, 571–579.V<strong>on</strong> Hagen, J. (1991): A note <strong>on</strong> the empirical effectiveness of formal fiscal restraints,Journal of Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 44, 199–210.V<strong>on</strong> Hagen, J. – Eichengreen, B. (1996): Federalism, fiscal restraints, and EuropeanM<strong>on</strong>etary Uni<strong>on</strong>, American Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 2, 86, 134–138.Weingast, B. (1979): A rati<strong>on</strong>al choice perspective <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>gressi<strong>on</strong>al norms. AmericanJournal of Political Science 23, 245–262.Weingast, B. – Shepsle, K. – Johnsen, C. (1981): The political ec<strong>on</strong>omy of benefitsand costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of PoliticalEc<strong>on</strong>omy 89, 642–664.41


Chapter 3Local Government in Denmark andthe 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>Jens Blom-HansenDepartment of Political ScienceAarhus University3.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong> and historical background 1Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> balances between self-<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> andcentral c<strong>on</strong>trol. On the <strong>on</strong>e hand, there is a traditi<strong>on</strong> of str<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Municipalities and regi<strong>on</strong>s are entrusted with morefuncti<strong>on</strong>s than in most countries, especially the <strong>municipal</strong>ities whichalso have independent taxati<strong>on</strong> rights. Furthermore, Denmark hasa vibrant democracy at the subnati<strong>on</strong>al level. On the other hand,Denmark also has a traditi<strong>on</strong> of central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trol andinterference in <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> affairs and of using <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> as aprovider of nati<strong>on</strong>al services.In Kjellberg’s (1995) terms, there has been a tensi<strong>on</strong> between anaut<strong>on</strong>omous model and an integrati<strong>on</strong>al model. According to thefirst model, central and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are two separate spheresof <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, which operate largely independently of each other.Local <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s’ primary functi<strong>on</strong> is to secure the traditi<strong>on</strong>alvalues of liberty, democratic participati<strong>on</strong>, and efficient provisi<strong>on</strong>of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services. According to the latter model, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>sform an integral part of the public sector, and their main role is toimplement nati<strong>on</strong>al policies.1 This chapter builds, where nothing else is menti<strong>on</strong>ed, <strong>on</strong> Blom-Hansen andHeeager (2010) and Blom-Hansen, Ibsen, Juul and Mouritzen (2012).43


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>The tensi<strong>on</strong> between the two roles for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s beganduring the era of absolutist royal rule (1660–1849). In the 1830sthe king established a new <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> system. In the urbanareas Denmark’s approximately eighty market towns were entrustedwith all <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> functi<strong>on</strong>s. In the rural areas a two-tiered structurewas established: around 1,100 parish <strong>municipal</strong>ities would handlebasic <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> functi<strong>on</strong>s such as primary educati<strong>on</strong> and social security,while county councils would be resp<strong>on</strong>sible for tasks that required alarger populati<strong>on</strong> basis such as hospital services. Although suffrageremained circumscribed, this system c<strong>on</strong>tained a rudimentary formof democracy. The market towns, the parish <strong>municipal</strong>ities, and thecounty councils all had elected bodies with some decisi<strong>on</strong>-makingcompetence. However, another important purpose of the system,securing implementati<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al policies, led to strict centralc<strong>on</strong>trol. In the market towns the mayor was appointed by the king,in the parish <strong>municipal</strong>ities, the pastor – as the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> branch of theabsolutist hierarchy – played an important role in schools and socialservices; in the county councils the governor (amtmand) was a central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> official who possessed wide powers or scrutiny over theparish <strong>municipal</strong>ities (Bundsgaard, 2000).After the end of absolutist rule and the introducti<strong>on</strong> of a democraticc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> in 1849, the values of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, democracy,and popular electi<strong>on</strong>s gained ground. Restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> suffrage weresomewhat eased in the 1850s; the role of the pastor was reduced inthe parish <strong>municipal</strong>ities in the 1860s; in 1908 an electoral <strong>reform</strong>gave women and servants voting rights in <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> electi<strong>on</strong>s andintroduced proporti<strong>on</strong>al electi<strong>on</strong> at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level; from 1919 mayorsin the market towns were no l<strong>on</strong>ger appointed by the king, but electedby the town council; and in the 1930s, the first inter-<strong>municipal</strong>equalizati<strong>on</strong> system was introduced (Dedenroth-Schou et al. 1991).As these examples show, changes did take place, but <strong>on</strong> a limitedscale. The basic features of the system introduced under absolutistrule remained unchanged until the large-scale <strong>reform</strong> in 1970.As noted by Page (1991:108–37) in a seven-country comparis<strong>on</strong>,Denmark had, c<strong>on</strong>trary to c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al categorizati<strong>on</strong>s, str<strong>on</strong>g traitsof a Napole<strong>on</strong>ic <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> system until the twentieth century.44


Jens Blom-HansenIn 1970 three sets of <strong>reform</strong> led to a complete overhaul of the Danish<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> system (Ingvartsen and Mikkelsen 1991). First, adramatic geographical c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> was initiated. More than 1,000parish <strong>municipal</strong>ities and eighty market towns were amalgamatedinto 275 new <strong>municipal</strong>ities, the twenty-five counties were mergedinto fourteen; and the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s abolished the old distincti<strong>on</strong>between rural and urban <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> systems. From then <strong>on</strong>,a new two-tiered system was introduced nati<strong>on</strong>wide: counties wereresp<strong>on</strong>sible for regi<strong>on</strong>al tasks, the new <strong>municipal</strong>ities for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>tasks. Only Copenhagen was left untouched and functi<strong>on</strong>ed as bothcounty and <strong>municipal</strong>ity in the new system. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, following theamalgamati<strong>on</strong>s, a <strong>reform</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> functi<strong>on</strong>s was carriedthrough over the next ten to twenty years. New tasks were transferredto <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s from the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and increasedaut<strong>on</strong>omy was introduced in the welfare areas that <strong>municipal</strong>itiesand counties already administered. Third, a financial <strong>reform</strong> wasimplemented. In a series of separate <strong>reform</strong>s, matching grants in anumber of areas were gradually transformed into <strong>on</strong>e general blockgrant which together with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> income tax became the main<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> income sources. In additi<strong>on</strong>, an advanced inter-<strong>municipal</strong>equalizati<strong>on</strong> system was established. These <strong>reform</strong>s strengthened<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> aut<strong>on</strong>omy, but also stressed the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ role as providersof nati<strong>on</strong>al services.The decades following the 1970 <strong>reform</strong> c<strong>on</strong>solidated these wideranging<strong>reform</strong>s. At the formal level no major changes took placeuntil the new overhaul in 2007. However, informally the integrati<strong>on</strong>of the <strong>municipal</strong>ities in the public sector was gradually tightened.Induced by the ec<strong>on</strong>omic crisis in the early 1980s the central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> increasingly included the ec<strong>on</strong>omic dispositi<strong>on</strong>s of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> sector in its macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policies. This wasd<strong>on</strong>e through informal so-called budgetary cooperati<strong>on</strong> with the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> associati<strong>on</strong>s. A system of annual negotiati<strong>on</strong>s endingwith agreements <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditure and taxati<strong>on</strong> level graduallytook shape and became a permanent trait of Danish inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>alrelati<strong>on</strong>s (Blom-Hansen, Ibsen, Juul and Mouritzen, 2012).45


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>In 2007 a new comprehensive <strong>reform</strong> was carried through. As in1970, the major ingredients were geographical c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> andredistributi<strong>on</strong> of functi<strong>on</strong>s across tiers in the public sector. The purposeof this chapter is to introduce this <strong>reform</strong> and its c<strong>on</strong>sequences ingreater detail.The chapter is structured as follows. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3.2 briefly introducesthe more permanent features of the Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> system.Secti<strong>on</strong>s 3.3 and 3.4 go into greater detail with the <strong>municipal</strong>amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s and the redistributi<strong>on</strong> of functi<strong>on</strong>s in 2007. Secti<strong>on</strong>3.5 provides an account of <strong>reform</strong>s undertaken since 2007. Secti<strong>on</strong>3.6 and 3.7 discuss the effects of the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> and the ensuingchallenges. Finally, secti<strong>on</strong> 3.8 c<strong>on</strong>cludes and discusses the need forfurther <strong>reform</strong>s and the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s <strong>on</strong>going evaluati<strong>on</strong> ofthe 2007 <strong>reform</strong>.3.2 Permanent features of Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>:Electi<strong>on</strong>s, political system, functi<strong>on</strong>s and financesAlthough the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> was comprehensive, it isimportant to keep in mind that important parts of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>system were not changed, and have remained stable since the early1970s.The first stable part is the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> electi<strong>on</strong> system. Municipal and regi<strong>on</strong>alelecti<strong>on</strong>s are held every four years and use the same system. Electi<strong>on</strong>sare proporti<strong>on</strong>al, and each <strong>municipal</strong>ity c<strong>on</strong>stitutes <strong>on</strong>e c<strong>on</strong>stituency.The number of seats in the <strong>municipal</strong> council is divided am<strong>on</strong>g theparties and lists by the D’H<strong>on</strong>dt method. There are no formal electoralthresholds, but because of the relatively low number of council seatsthere are relatively high natural thresholds. 2 Candidates are selected2 The <strong>municipal</strong>ities decide the size of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> council, but must respect theserules: In <strong>municipal</strong>ities with more than 20,000 inhabitants the council must have between19 and 31 members; in <strong>municipal</strong>ities with less than 20,000 inhabitants the council musthave between 9 and 31 members; in Copenhagen the <strong>municipal</strong> council can have up to 55members.46


Jens Blom-Hansenby parties or lists, who can nominate up to four pers<strong>on</strong>s more than thesize of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> council. Local electi<strong>on</strong>s result in multiparty systemsat the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level. Local branches of nati<strong>on</strong>al parties have traditi<strong>on</strong>allydominated <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> politics, in particular the Social Democratic Party,the Liberal Party and the C<strong>on</strong>servative Party. Local lists have alsobeen frequent in Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> politics, but both the 1970 and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s have made their life difficult. Local partysystems have increasingly become ‘nati<strong>on</strong>alised’, especially afterthe 2007 <strong>reform</strong>. Table 1 shows the present distributi<strong>on</strong> of the totalnumber of Danish <strong>municipal</strong> seats am<strong>on</strong>g the political parties.Table 1Nati<strong>on</strong>al result of the Danish <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong>sShare of seats (per cent)Red-Green Alliance 0.6Socialist People’s Party 13.8Social Democratic Party 32.5Social Liberals 2Liberal Alliance 0Liberal Party 28.3C<strong>on</strong>servative People’s Party 10.6Danish People’s Party 7.5Local lists 4.4Schleswigian Party 0.2N=100 per cent 2,468Source: Statistics DenmarkAfter electi<strong>on</strong>s, the political positi<strong>on</strong>s in the <strong>municipal</strong> politicalsystem are filled. This system c<strong>on</strong>stitutes the sec<strong>on</strong>d permanent partof the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> system. It c<strong>on</strong>sists of three political bodies:a council, a set of standing committees, and a mayor. The councilc<strong>on</strong>sists of 9–31 members, it is the supreme <strong>municipal</strong> body, and maybe c<strong>on</strong>sidered the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> legislature. Executive power is exercised in acommittee system with a divisi<strong>on</strong> of labour between the mayor and47


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>the standing sectoral committees. The mayor is elected by and am<strong>on</strong>gthe council members <strong>on</strong> a simple majority basis, is the formal headof the <strong>municipal</strong> administrati<strong>on</strong> and chairs the council’s financialcommittee. The members of the standing committees are also electedby and am<strong>on</strong>g the council members, but <strong>on</strong> a proporti<strong>on</strong>al basis. Thecommittees are resp<strong>on</strong>sible for the day-to-day administrati<strong>on</strong> withinthe various policy sectors. The chairmen of the committees are electedby the committees <strong>on</strong> a simple majority basis. Although the chairmen<strong>on</strong>ly have few formal powers, they can be quite powerful sincec<strong>on</strong>siderable influence is often delegated to them in practice. Together,the mayor and the chairmen of the sectoral standing committeesc<strong>on</strong>stitute the executive power in the Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>system. They are the functi<strong>on</strong>al equivalent of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in thenati<strong>on</strong>al system (Skjæveland et al., 2007). The <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> political systemis assisted by a large professi<strong>on</strong>al administrati<strong>on</strong>. In formal terms it isa unitary service directed by the mayor, but in practice it has str<strong>on</strong>gsectoral traits since it is divided into departments and, in substantialmatters, the departments do not answer to the mayor, but to thecommittees.Table 2Municipal politicians and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrators over time1966 1990 2010Number of <strong>municipal</strong> politicians 10,005 4,677 2,468Number of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrators 46,020 451,916 527,775Number of administrators perpoliticianSource: Blom-Hansen, Ibsen, Juul and Mouritzen (2012: 158)4.6 96.6 213.8Since the size of the <strong>municipal</strong> council has <strong>on</strong>ly increased slightlyover time, the <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s in 1970 and 2007 havemeant a radically decreasing number of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> councillors. At thesame time, the <strong>municipal</strong> administrati<strong>on</strong> has grown c<strong>on</strong>siderablyover time, which has led to a dramatic increase in the number ofadministrators per <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> politician, cf. Table 2. This development is48


Jens Blom-Hansenseen by some as a rising challenge to the democratic c<strong>on</strong>trol of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrati<strong>on</strong> (Blom-Hansen, Ibsen, Juul and Mouritzen 2012:157–175).At the regi<strong>on</strong>al level, counties and <strong>municipal</strong>ities had similarpolitical systems until the 2007 <strong>reform</strong>, but now there are importantdifferences. The regi<strong>on</strong>al council, which has 41 members, is thesupreme body. There is also a regi<strong>on</strong>al chairman, a post that iscomparable to the <strong>municipal</strong> mayor. However, the regi<strong>on</strong>s do nothave a committee system. They may, but are not obliged to, leavedaily administrative matters to an executive committee, but cannotestablish standing sectoral committees like the <strong>municipal</strong>ities and theold counties before 2007.Turning to functi<strong>on</strong>s, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities and, to a lesser extent, theregi<strong>on</strong>s are heavyweights in the Danish public sector. Althoughthe 2007 <strong>reform</strong> redistributed a number of functi<strong>on</strong>s across thetiers in the public sector, the basic divisi<strong>on</strong> remains stable. Thisc<strong>on</strong>stitutes the third permanent part of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> system.In total, <strong>municipal</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>s amount to more than half of all publicexpenditure in Denmark and have d<strong>on</strong>e so for many years. Themost important <strong>municipal</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>s are – and have always been –basic welfare services: child care, primary educati<strong>on</strong>, and eldercare. In additi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>municipal</strong>ities have traditi<strong>on</strong>ally administeredsocial transfers such as housing benefits, social security and old agepensi<strong>on</strong>s. Furthermore, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities have – and have alwayshad – important resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities in the utility area (garbage collecti<strong>on</strong>,<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> roads) and, since more recent times, in culture and recreati<strong>on</strong>(libraries, theatres, sports facilities). In additi<strong>on</strong> to these traditi<strong>on</strong>altasks, the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> transferred a number of functi<strong>on</strong>s from the oldcounties to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities. This is explained in more detail belowin secti<strong>on</strong> 3.4. The 2007 <strong>reform</strong> means that, in terms of functi<strong>on</strong>s, theDanish <strong>municipal</strong>ities today are str<strong>on</strong>ger than ever. Table 3 showsthe budget shares of the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ present tasks. It is evidentthat, according to this yardstick, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> welfare is their most importantfuncti<strong>on</strong>.49


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>At the regi<strong>on</strong>al level, the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> stripped the old counties ofalmost all their functi<strong>on</strong>s, except health care, which has always beentheir most important task. As is also evident from Table 3, health care(hospitals and primary health care by general practiti<strong>on</strong>ers) is by farthe most important task for the five Danish regi<strong>on</strong>s. In additi<strong>on</strong>, theyare resp<strong>on</strong>sible for running specialized social instituti<strong>on</strong>s and have acoordinating functi<strong>on</strong> in the regi<strong>on</strong>al development area.Table 3The functi<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s (grosscurrent and capital expenditure, budget 2012)MunicipalitiesMill.DKKPercent Regi<strong>on</strong>s Mill.DKKPercentUrban and envir<strong>on</strong>mental affairs 13,150 3 Health care 113,268 92Public utilities 9,471 2 Social affairs 4,705 4Traffic and infrastructure 15,422 3Regi<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment3,006 3Educati<strong>on</strong> and culture 75,829 17 Administrati<strong>on</strong> 1,942 2Health care 26,094 6Social affairs 266,442 60Administrati<strong>on</strong> 42,244 9Sum 448,652 100 Sum 122,558 100Source: Statistics DenmarkFinally, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> system of finance has remained stablesince the 1970s. Municipal and regi<strong>on</strong>al expenditures are financed bydifferent income sources, cf. Table 4. At the <strong>municipal</strong> level, taxesare the main source of revenue. The most important <strong>on</strong>e is the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>income tax, and <strong>municipal</strong>ities are free to decide the rate withinthe limits set by the annual agreement between their associati<strong>on</strong>and the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. For many years these agreementshave stipulated that the average <strong>municipal</strong> tax rate is to be keptc<strong>on</strong>stant, but individual <strong>municipal</strong>ities may adjust their rates upanddownwards. In recent years more and more c<strong>on</strong>trols have beenimposed up<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxati<strong>on</strong>, which has led to a c<strong>on</strong>siderable lack of50


Jens Blom-Hansenflexibility in <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxati<strong>on</strong>. The c<strong>on</strong>trol system is explained in moredetail in secti<strong>on</strong> 3.7. The average <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> income tax rate was 24.9 percent in 2012. The income taxati<strong>on</strong> right is traditi<strong>on</strong>ally c<strong>on</strong>sideredthe cornerst<strong>on</strong>e of Danish <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Municipalities alsolevy property and corporate taxes, but they generate far less revenue.The sec<strong>on</strong>d most important <strong>municipal</strong> income source is grants fromthe central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>: matching grants to help finance <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> transferpayments and a general block grant. Third, <strong>municipal</strong>ities levy feeswithin the utility area and the social service areas. Finally, borrowingis generally forbidden, but exempti<strong>on</strong>s are granted in a number ofareas specified by central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> regulati<strong>on</strong>.At the regi<strong>on</strong>al level, there are no taxes after the 2007 <strong>reform</strong>, sogrants from both the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities arenow the main regi<strong>on</strong>al income source. Fees are also important, andthey are levied <strong>on</strong> the <strong>municipal</strong>ities for their use of regi<strong>on</strong>al socialinstituti<strong>on</strong>s and hospitals. Borrowing is generally forbidden at theregi<strong>on</strong>al level but, again, some exempti<strong>on</strong>s are allowed by the central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Table 4 The <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> system of finance (budget 2012)MunicipalitiesRegi<strong>on</strong>sMill. DKK Per cent Mill. DKK Per centTaxes 233,106 52 - -Grants 145,379 32 108,074 88Fees 58,420 13 12,855 11Net borrowing 2,316 1 -417 0Other* 9,430 2 2,047 2Total 448,651 100 122,559 100* ‘Other’ includes sale of capital assets, net interest payments, and use of liquid means.Source: Statistics Denmark51


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>3.3 The <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s in 2007When the Liberal Party and the C<strong>on</strong>servative People’s Party tookover the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Denmark in 2001 after ten years of SocialDemocratic rule no-<strong>on</strong>e imagined that a large-scale <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>was underway. The issue had not played any role in the electi<strong>on</strong>campaign, and it was not included in the formal <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> platformnegotiated between the Liberal and C<strong>on</strong>servative party leaders.N<strong>on</strong>etheless, the issue so<strong>on</strong> became pertinent. In the summer of 2002the questi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s and alleged inefficiency insmall <strong>municipal</strong>ities was intensively discussed in the media, and the<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s resp<strong>on</strong>se was to appoint a commissi<strong>on</strong> to investigatethe need for a new <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>.One and a half years later the commissi<strong>on</strong> had completed atwo thousand page report (Strukturkommissi<strong>on</strong>en 2004). Thecommissi<strong>on</strong>’s answer was a clear yes, there is a need for a new<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>. However, it was less clear which type of <strong>reform</strong>was necessary. This vagueness was no coincidence. The commissi<strong>on</strong>was deliberately asked not to be too specific but <strong>on</strong>ly to discuss prosand c<strong>on</strong>s of different scenarios. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> wanted to keep openthe political opti<strong>on</strong>s.After an intensive negotiati<strong>on</strong> process in the spring of 2004, it wasclear that broad parliamentary support for a <strong>reform</strong> did not exist, sothe <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> entered into a narrow compromise with the rightwingDanish People’s Party (Regeringen 2004). This compromisegave the <strong>municipal</strong>ities six m<strong>on</strong>ths to find amalgamati<strong>on</strong> partnersand establish new <strong>municipal</strong>ities with at least 30,000 inhabitants. Aso-called cat flap door was introduced for small <strong>municipal</strong>ities withless than 20,000 inhabitants that did not want to amalgamate, inwhich case they had to enter a formal agreement with a neighboring<strong>municipal</strong>ity about a number of specified tasks. The idea behind thisplan was to give the <strong>municipal</strong>ities relatively short time to settle theamalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. It was made clear that the alternative to voluntaryamalgamati<strong>on</strong>s was some sort of central interventi<strong>on</strong>, although theexact nature of this threat was never specified.52


Jens Blom-HansenThese tactics paid off. Each <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> situati<strong>on</strong> had its own dynamics, butthe fear of ending up as a benchwarmer helped the process al<strong>on</strong>g.To many observers’ surprise, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> amalgamati<strong>on</strong> agreements werequickly c<strong>on</strong>cluded. Already by late summer 2004 eleven <strong>municipal</strong>itiesannounced that they had agreed to enter closed amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s,which meant that they c<strong>on</strong>sidered their agreements final and notopen to additi<strong>on</strong>al partners. However, these early movers ended upas relatively small <strong>municipal</strong>ities <strong>on</strong> the new <strong>municipal</strong> map wherethe average number of inhabitants is approximately 55,000. Theearly movers included Billund and Kerteminde with less than 30,000inhabitants, Odsherred and Faxe with less than 40,000, and Thisted,Skive, Hedensted, and Syddjurs with less than 50,000 inhabitants.The <strong>municipal</strong>ities which wanted to use the cat flap door and enter aformal agreement with a larger neighboring <strong>municipal</strong>ity c<strong>on</strong>stituteda special problem. They had to persuade a large new <strong>municipal</strong>ityto make this arrangement, but often the large <strong>municipal</strong>ity preferredthe small neighbor to become a part of their new <strong>municipal</strong>ity ratherthan to c<strong>on</strong>tinue as a small neighbor with a complicated cooperativearrangement. In practice, the cat flap door turned out to be narrow, andthe small <strong>municipal</strong>ities were quietly swallowed by their neighbours.In the end, <strong>on</strong>ly seven of the 190 old <strong>municipal</strong>ities, which before the<strong>reform</strong> had less than 20,000 inhabitants, c<strong>on</strong>tinued as independent<strong>municipal</strong>ities. Five are islands which already in the parliamentary<strong>reform</strong> compromise were menti<strong>on</strong>ed as candidates for the cat flapdoor. Only two other <strong>municipal</strong>ities, Dragør and Vallensbæk in theCopenhagen regi<strong>on</strong>, succeeded in squeezing through the cat flap door.The final result was that <strong>on</strong>ly 33 <strong>municipal</strong>ities c<strong>on</strong>tinued unchanged,while the remaining 237 were more or less voluntarily amalgamatedinto 65 new large entities. The amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s were preceded <strong>on</strong> theisland of Bornholm, whose five <strong>municipal</strong>ities were amalgamatedinto <strong>on</strong>e already in 2003, and <strong>on</strong> the island of Ærø, whose two<strong>municipal</strong>ities were amalgamated in 2006. On the island of Langelandthe three <strong>municipal</strong>ities had decided to amalgamate prior to thegeneral <strong>reform</strong>, but did not make their decisi<strong>on</strong> effective until 2007and thus followed the general time schedule. The final result appears in53


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>Table 5, which shows that the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s were mostly a provincialphenomen<strong>on</strong>. In the capital regi<strong>on</strong>, where the <strong>municipal</strong>ities wererelatively large already before the <strong>reform</strong>, <strong>on</strong>ly about every fourth<strong>municipal</strong>ity was amalgamated. Today there are speculati<strong>on</strong>s in theunchanged <strong>municipal</strong>ities in the Copenhagen area that the decisi<strong>on</strong>not to amalgamate may not have been wise, and that they may havebecome too small in the new <strong>municipal</strong> landscape. Several have toyedwith the idea of amalgamating with their equally-sized neighbor.N<strong>on</strong>e, however, have indicated any wish to be amalgamated with the<strong>municipal</strong>ity of Copenhagen, probably fearing that this would end ina swallow up without any influence <strong>on</strong> the amalgamati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s.However, so far no new amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s have been undertaken.Table 5The 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s divided according toregi<strong>on</strong>Regi<strong>on</strong>No. of new<strong>municipal</strong>itiesPer centamalgamatedAverage no. ofinhabitantsCapital 29 28 56,260Sealand 17 82 47,409Southern Denmark 22 82 53,810Central Denmark 19 84 63,841North Denmark 11 82 52,455Sum 98 66 55,217Source: Blom-Hansen, Ibsen, Juul and Mouritzen (2012: 80)In hindsight, the <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong> process was surprisinglysmooth. The new <strong>municipal</strong>ities even ended up much larger thanboth expected and desired by the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Its goal was<strong>municipal</strong>ities with approximately 30,000 inhabitants, but as Table5 shows, this goal was exceeded to a remarkable extent. Apparently,the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s were difficult to stop <strong>on</strong>ce the process was started.54


Jens Blom-HansenAt the regi<strong>on</strong>al level, the old fourteen counties were amalgamatedinto five new regi<strong>on</strong>s, including the two metropolitan <strong>municipal</strong>itiesCopenhagen and Frederiksberg, which until the <strong>reform</strong> had functi<strong>on</strong>edas both county and <strong>municipal</strong>ity. However, while the <strong>municipal</strong>amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s were semi-voluntary, the regi<strong>on</strong>al mergers weredictated by the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The number of regi<strong>on</strong>s, theirboundaries, names, and the new regi<strong>on</strong>al capitals were all decided bythe central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.3.4 The accompanying redistributi<strong>on</strong> of functi<strong>on</strong>sacross tiersThe <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>stituted the structural part of the2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>. The functi<strong>on</strong>al part of the <strong>reform</strong> entaileda series of both centralizing and decentralizing changes of thedistributi<strong>on</strong> of functi<strong>on</strong>s am<strong>on</strong>g the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, the new<strong>municipal</strong>ities and the new regi<strong>on</strong>s.In the area of taxati<strong>on</strong>, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities have traditi<strong>on</strong>ally beenresp<strong>on</strong>sible for the assessment of property values and taxable incomes,both pers<strong>on</strong>al and corporate incomes. This may sound strange becausethese are tasks where equality before the law is obviously moreimportant than adapti<strong>on</strong> to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> needs and preferences. But in the olddays, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> knowledge was also important in order to assess farmers’incomes, and equality before the law was ensured by an arm’s lengthprinciple. The <strong>municipal</strong> tax administrati<strong>on</strong> was independent fromthe <strong>municipal</strong> council and the mayor when deciding individual cases.When the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> transferred all tax assessmentfuncti<strong>on</strong>s to the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, it was the culminati<strong>on</strong> of a seriesof <strong>reform</strong>s where parts of the tax assessment functi<strong>on</strong>s were graduallycentralized. In 1998 corporate income tax assessment was transferredto the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and in 2002 property value assessmentwas also centralized.55


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>However, from the perspective of the <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> thesecentralizing changes in the tax area were remarkable. As in manyother areas there had been speculati<strong>on</strong>s before the <strong>reform</strong> that thesmall <strong>municipal</strong>ities had problems solving their tasks in a fullyqualified way. In the tax area these speculati<strong>on</strong>s had more empiricalbacking than in the other areas, where the <strong>reform</strong> advocates neverreally succeeded in documenting problems in the small <strong>municipal</strong>ities.Nevertheless, the tax area was the <strong>on</strong>ly area where amalgamati<strong>on</strong>swere not the soluti<strong>on</strong> to the problems in the small <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Asa rare excepti<strong>on</strong>, the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> instead chose to transfer thetask out of the <strong>municipal</strong> system.Apart from the tax area, the functi<strong>on</strong>al part of the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong><strong>reform</strong> resulted in a c<strong>on</strong>siderable transferral of tasks to the new<strong>municipal</strong>ities. Most came from the old counties, most importantlyspecialized social services and health care.Within the area of specialized social services, which includesinstituti<strong>on</strong>s for the physically and mentally handicapped, the 2007<strong>reform</strong> presented a new soluti<strong>on</strong> to a problem that has been presentever since the <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> in 1970, namely the tensi<strong>on</strong> betweengeneral and special social services. Until 2007 the special services,which are targeted at narrow client groups, were placed with thecounties, while the <strong>municipal</strong>ities took care of general social servicestargeted at broad groups of clients. However, the special and generalservices cannot be run independently of each other, and this problemhas given rise to many coordinati<strong>on</strong> problems between the countiesand the <strong>municipal</strong>ities over time. It has also given rise to speculati<strong>on</strong>sof strategic behavior due to complicated co-financing systems. The2007 <strong>reform</strong> places the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for both special and generalsocial services with the new <strong>municipal</strong>ities. From then <strong>on</strong>, they areresp<strong>on</strong>sible for referring all handicapped pers<strong>on</strong>s to instituti<strong>on</strong>alizedservices. However, the idea was that the new regi<strong>on</strong>s should maintainresp<strong>on</strong>sibility for running the most specialized instituti<strong>on</strong>s, whichneed a larger populati<strong>on</strong> base than even the new large <strong>municipal</strong>itieshave. Coordinati<strong>on</strong> between the regi<strong>on</strong>s and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities wouldtake place in a new system of negotiated agreements at the regi<strong>on</strong>al56


Jens Blom-Hansenlevel between the regi<strong>on</strong> and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities within the regi<strong>on</strong>.The final soluti<strong>on</strong> to the old coordinati<strong>on</strong> problem was thereforeunder no circumstances in sight. But the role of the regi<strong>on</strong>s turnedout to be much smaller than the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> expected. The<strong>municipal</strong>ities were given the choice to either take over the oldcounty instituti<strong>on</strong>s or let them be transferred to the new regi<strong>on</strong>s. Tothe <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s surprise the <strong>municipal</strong>ities engaged in c<strong>on</strong>siderable‘empire building’ and decided to take over almost all the counties’old special instituti<strong>on</strong>s. They could do this without incurring newcosts, but had to respect that these instituti<strong>on</strong>s should be open toclients from other <strong>municipal</strong>ities and that capacity and prices hadto be coordinated in the new agreements between the regi<strong>on</strong>s and<strong>municipal</strong>ities. This meant that many <strong>municipal</strong>ities ended up withinstituti<strong>on</strong>s for which they did not have enough clients of their own.This again meant that a market was created where <strong>municipal</strong>ities selland buy places in specialized social instituti<strong>on</strong>s.Within the health care area, all primary (general practiti<strong>on</strong>ers) andsec<strong>on</strong>dary services (hospitals) have traditi<strong>on</strong>ally been the counties’resp<strong>on</strong>sibility. The health care part of the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> was preparedby a special working group that investigated three organizati<strong>on</strong>almodels: A <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>, a regi<strong>on</strong>al, and a nati<strong>on</strong>al health care system. Theworking group recommended that health care c<strong>on</strong>tinued as a regi<strong>on</strong>alsystem, although it wanted fewer regi<strong>on</strong>al entities (Indenrigs- ogSundhedsministerens rådgivende udvalg 2003). The commissi<strong>on</strong>resp<strong>on</strong>sible for preparing the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> more or less adopted theworking group’s c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>, and ultimately so did the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.So although alternative and quite radical organizati<strong>on</strong>al models wereanalyzed, there was never any serious threat to the regi<strong>on</strong>al healthcare system. However, the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> nevertheless resulted in notinsignificant adjustments of the existing system. It both transferredsome health care functi<strong>on</strong>s to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities and made themfinancially co-resp<strong>on</strong>sible for hospital services. As to health carefuncti<strong>on</strong>s, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities took over rehabilitati<strong>on</strong> of hospitalpatients, health preventi<strong>on</strong> and promoti<strong>on</strong> of healthy life styles.As to finances, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities became financially resp<strong>on</strong>siblefor approximately 30 per cent of the costs of having their citizens57


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>treated at the regi<strong>on</strong>al hospitals. The overall idea was to provide the<strong>municipal</strong>ities with an incentive to solve their health tasks efficiently.If they are efficient, hospital treatments may be avoided, and becauseof the new co-financing arrangement, this again means that theysave m<strong>on</strong>ey. However, this idea rests up<strong>on</strong> quite heroic assumpti<strong>on</strong>s(Pedersen, 2005). First, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities do not refer patients to thehospitals, which means that there is no automatic c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong> betweenthe <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ and the hospitals’ activities. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the <strong>municipal</strong>share of hospital costs is <strong>on</strong>ly about 30 per cent. This means that the<strong>municipal</strong>ities <strong>on</strong>ly save m<strong>on</strong>ey if their alternative soluti<strong>on</strong> costs lessthan <strong>on</strong>e third of a hospital treatment. To support relati<strong>on</strong>s between<strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s in the new system, the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>introduced a formal requirement that they c<strong>on</strong>clude cooperati<strong>on</strong>agreements with each other that specify practical arrangements.From the perspective of the regi<strong>on</strong>s, the functi<strong>on</strong>al part of the2007 <strong>reform</strong> was a set-back. First, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities were givenresp<strong>on</strong>sibilities within their traditi<strong>on</strong>al main functi<strong>on</strong>, health care.Sec<strong>on</strong>d, almost all their other traditi<strong>on</strong>al functi<strong>on</strong>s were taken away.Specialized social services were transferred to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities, andall their instituti<strong>on</strong>s within sec<strong>on</strong>dary educati<strong>on</strong> were transferred tothe central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.In sum, the functi<strong>on</strong>al part of the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> entailed a c<strong>on</strong>siderablestrengthening of the functi<strong>on</strong>al base of both the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>and the new <strong>municipal</strong>ities, while the new regi<strong>on</strong>s were createdas reduced versi<strong>on</strong>s of the old counties. A c<strong>on</strong>siderable numberof employees in the <strong>municipal</strong>ities and counties got a new publicemployer and some had to accept a l<strong>on</strong>ger commute to work becausetheir work place was relocated as part of the <strong>reform</strong>. However, no<strong>on</strong>elost their job because of the <strong>reform</strong> since employment rights werelegally protected. 33 According to the Danish law <strong>on</strong> employees’ rights in case of transfer ofundertakings (lov om virksomhedsoverdragelse) employees cannot be laid off becausetheir job is transferred to another employer (but it does not protect against dismissal forother reas<strong>on</strong>s). This law implements EU rules <strong>on</strong> safeguarding of employees’ rights.58


Jens Blom-Hansen3.5 Reforms since the <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> in 2007The labour marketFour major <strong>reform</strong>s have been undertaken since the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong><strong>reform</strong>. The first is a further decentralizati<strong>on</strong> of functi<strong>on</strong>s to the<strong>municipal</strong>ities. In the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s original <strong>reform</strong> plans,employment policies within the labour market area were to be fullydecentralized to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Traditi<strong>on</strong>ally, employment policyhas been a divided area in Denmark. The central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> hasbeen resp<strong>on</strong>sible for pers<strong>on</strong>s insured in an unemployment fund, while<strong>municipal</strong>ities have been resp<strong>on</strong>sible for uninsured pers<strong>on</strong>s, whohave to rely <strong>on</strong> social security in case of unemployment. In 2007,the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> wanted to create a unified system and decentralizeit to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities. The Social Democratic Party opposed theidea, however, and the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> therefore aband<strong>on</strong>ed it, hopingto lure them into backing the whole <strong>reform</strong> project. Even though theplan failed, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> did not re-introduce the original ideaof decentralizing employment policies (Christiansen and Klitgaard,2008: 159–193). Most observers thought that yet an attempt to unifythe employment system had failed, but in the autumn of 2008 the<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> caught most actors by surprise and successfully raisedits original proposal in the parliamentary negotiati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the 2009finance bill. Again it was a narrow compromise that did not includethe Social Democratic Party, but <strong>on</strong>ly the Danish People’s Party andthe new center party Liberal Alliance. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic incentives play alarge role in the new instituti<strong>on</strong>al set-up. The <strong>municipal</strong>ities havenot <strong>on</strong>ly taken over the employment services, but also the financialresp<strong>on</strong>sibility for unemployment benefits. This allegedly providesthem with an incentive to deliver efficient employment policies,because if unemployment goes down, the reducti<strong>on</strong> in expenditures<strong>on</strong> unemployment benefits ends up as <strong>municipal</strong> savings. However,in reality, it is relatively difficult for the individual <strong>municipal</strong>ityto influence the employment situati<strong>on</strong>, which primarily depends<strong>on</strong> the nati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omic situati<strong>on</strong>. And macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policy isstill a central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>sibility. This means that the newresp<strong>on</strong>sibilities within the employment area carry c<strong>on</strong>siderable59


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>ec<strong>on</strong>omic risks for the individual <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Not surprisingly,this fact made the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong> demand anec<strong>on</strong>omic safety net. This was granted in the form of a complicatedsystem of grants and reimbursement schemes. From the perspectiveof the individual <strong>municipal</strong>ity this makes a lot of sense, but the priceis that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> incentive to effectively combat unemployment isblunted.The administrati<strong>on</strong> of transfer paymentsThe sec<strong>on</strong>d <strong>reform</strong> is an instance of centralizati<strong>on</strong> driven bydigitalizati<strong>on</strong> and scale effects. Traditi<strong>on</strong>ally, Danish <strong>municipal</strong>itieshave administered a number of transfer payment schemes even inareas without <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> aut<strong>on</strong>omy, e.g. old age pensi<strong>on</strong>. Starting in 2012the practical administrati<strong>on</strong> of all transfer payments that are fullyspecified by legal regulati<strong>on</strong> are transferred from the <strong>municipal</strong>itiesto a new organizati<strong>on</strong>, Udbetaling Danmark. More specifically, thisorganizati<strong>on</strong> takes over the administrati<strong>on</strong> of family allowances,maternal benefits, housing benefits, early retirement benefits, andold age pensi<strong>on</strong>s. The <strong>reform</strong> was the result of pressure for higherefficiency by means of digitalizati<strong>on</strong> and large-scale operati<strong>on</strong>s. Thispressure had for some years been c<strong>on</strong>fined to the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>apparatus and led to various <strong>reform</strong>s, including the establishment ofcentral service centers taking over administrative tasks such a wageadministrati<strong>on</strong>, accounting, IT service, and travel administrati<strong>on</strong> forthe central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> ministries. But the pressure to obtain theseapparently free savings was then directed to the <strong>municipal</strong> sector, andso<strong>on</strong> the questi<strong>on</strong> was raised whether the administrati<strong>on</strong> of transferpayments could not be made more efficient by means of large-scaleoperati<strong>on</strong>s and digitalizati<strong>on</strong>. After several years of discussi<strong>on</strong> acompromise between the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>alassociati<strong>on</strong> was reached. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> succeeded in centralizingthe administrati<strong>on</strong> of these transfer payments in five centers to beestablished in different parts of the country, and the <strong>municipal</strong>itiessucceeded in keeping the savings from the <strong>reform</strong>. Furthermore,the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong> succeeded in avoiding a fullcentral <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> take-over. The future administrati<strong>on</strong> is not placed60


Jens Blom-Hansenin a central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> agency – like other central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>transfer payment schemes, e.g. student benefits – but with a thenew organizati<strong>on</strong>, Udbetaling Danmark. This is a self-governingorganizati<strong>on</strong> with a majority of <strong>municipal</strong> representatives in itsgoverning board.Budget and account systemsThe third <strong>reform</strong> is an example of a silent change that has g<strong>on</strong>eunnoticed by the public, but which may have important implicati<strong>on</strong>s.In the wake of the 1970 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> a standardized <strong>municipal</strong>budget and account system was introduced. This was a big stepforward because it made it possible to measure total expenditurespent by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> sector and to compare individual<strong>municipal</strong>ities with each other <strong>on</strong> a standardized basis. The systemwas based <strong>on</strong> the cash flow principle, according to which expenditureis measured when it is spent. This principle favors macroec<strong>on</strong>omicc<strong>on</strong>trol because it precisely measures the ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity impulsefrom the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> sector. It also makes it easier to estimatetax needs and to plan liquidity usage. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, systems based <strong>on</strong>the accrual principle, which measures costs rather than expenditure,make it easier to estimate the precise costs of public producti<strong>on</strong> whichis advantageous when, for example, public services are c<strong>on</strong>tractedout. The debate about the relative pros and c<strong>on</strong>s of the cash flowand accrual principle is l<strong>on</strong>g-standing, and public budget and accountsystems have shifted back and forth between the two principles overtime. For example, in the wake of the breakthrough of Keynesianismafter World War II many countries opted for the cash flow system,which facilitates macroec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>trol policies. Today, manycountries return to the accrual principle because comparis<strong>on</strong>s of publicand private service producti<strong>on</strong>, c<strong>on</strong>tracting out, and privatizati<strong>on</strong> aremore politically salient phenomena (Blöndal, 2003). In Denmark,the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> has recently opted for the accrual principle,although with important excepti<strong>on</strong>s (Finansministeriet, 2003). Thesituati<strong>on</strong> in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> sector has been discussed between<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>for more than ten years. The accrual principle has been graduallyintroduced, first in the area of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public utilities and then expanded,but <strong>on</strong>ly to accounts, not budgets. But the <strong>municipal</strong> budget and accountsystem was changed to make both accrual accounting and budgetingpossible. However, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>, worriedabout the administrative costs of this <strong>reform</strong>, increasingly took upthe issue in the annual negotiati<strong>on</strong>s with the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, andin 2010 succeeded in making the choice between the two systemsvoluntary for the individual <strong>municipal</strong>ity. The situati<strong>on</strong> today is thataccrual budgeting and accounting is possible in the <strong>municipal</strong> sector,but not obligatory. 4Inter-<strong>municipal</strong> equalizati<strong>on</strong> schemesThe fourth and final major <strong>reform</strong> after the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>c<strong>on</strong>cerns the inter-<strong>municipal</strong> equalizati<strong>on</strong> system. This system was<strong>reform</strong>ed in c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong> with the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> and then again in 2009and 2012. The latter <strong>reform</strong>s were the result of pressure that had builtup as a c<strong>on</strong>sequence of the 2007 <strong>reform</strong>. The equalizati<strong>on</strong> systemtransfers large amounts from rich to poor <strong>municipal</strong>ities in orderto enable the <strong>municipal</strong>ities to offer <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services to their citizensat comparable tax prices. Although there is c<strong>on</strong>sensus am<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>politicians about the idea behind the system, the equalizati<strong>on</strong> leveland the exact measurement of expenditure needs and tax bases is,not surprisingly, c<strong>on</strong>troversial since these issues may have importantec<strong>on</strong>omic implicati<strong>on</strong>s, and because the situati<strong>on</strong> is a zero-sumgame where gains for <strong>on</strong>e <strong>municipal</strong>ity mean losses for another. Inthe wake of the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> a large-scale <strong>reform</strong> of the equalizati<strong>on</strong>system was undertaken. Changes that had been discussed for yearswere carried out. Most importantly, the distributi<strong>on</strong> mechanism ofthe general block grant was changed from tax base to number ofinhabitants, corporate taxati<strong>on</strong> was included in the equalizati<strong>on</strong>of tax bases, special grants were abolished, the measurement ofexpenditure needs was changed, and the overall equalizati<strong>on</strong> level4 All <strong>municipal</strong>ities must register expenditure according to the cash-flow principlein the uniform budget and account system. The system allows voluntary extra registrati<strong>on</strong>saccording to the accrual principle.62


Jens Blom-Hansenwas increased. The exact distributi<strong>on</strong>al implicati<strong>on</strong>s of this <strong>reform</strong>were difficult to estimate precisely because of the simultaneousamalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. However, a number of poor <strong>municipal</strong>ities felt thatthe <strong>reform</strong> was not far-reaching enough. ‘Equalizati<strong>on</strong> rebelli<strong>on</strong>s’have been seen before in Danish inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al relati<strong>on</strong>s, but thistime the poor <strong>municipal</strong>ities were more vehement and insistent than<strong>on</strong> previous occasi<strong>on</strong>s. Maybe the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s played a role here,because before 2007 the poor <strong>municipal</strong>ities tended to be small rural<strong>municipal</strong>ities without much influence in nati<strong>on</strong>al politics. But in thepost-2007 system poor <strong>municipal</strong>ities have more political muscle.An alliance of 39 <strong>municipal</strong>ities launched an equalizati<strong>on</strong> campaignagainst the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, andthe Danish Parliament, Folketinget. Their main target of criticismwas the measurement of expenditure needs, which they felt led tounder-compensati<strong>on</strong> of their true needs. The campaign paid off. Afirst resp<strong>on</strong>se was given in 2009 when the measurement of the socioec<strong>on</strong>omicexpenditure needs was adjusted. This led to some gainsfor the poor <strong>municipal</strong>ities, but far from satisfied ‘the 39’, as theywere now known. In 2011 the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> changed, and a coaliti<strong>on</strong>led by the Social Democratic Party took over from the Liberal-C<strong>on</strong>servative <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. ‘The 39’ intensified their campaign,and the new <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> agreed to an overhaul of the equalizati<strong>on</strong>system. This was d<strong>on</strong>e in 2012, and changes will become effectivein 2013. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> tried to downplay the implicati<strong>on</strong>s of theoverhaul and labeled it an adjustment rather than a <strong>reform</strong>, sincechanges were (mostly) kept to a recalibrati<strong>on</strong> of the measurementsof expenditure needs. However, seen from the perspective of theindividual <strong>municipal</strong>ities the changes were c<strong>on</strong>siderable. Gains fora number of poor <strong>municipal</strong>ities exceed 0.5 income tax percentagepoints, while losses for rich <strong>municipal</strong>ities in some cases are as higha 0.3–0.4 income tax percentage points (LF 191/2012).3.6 Effects of the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>This secti<strong>on</strong> discusses three types of c<strong>on</strong>sequences of the 2007<strong>reform</strong>. First, the implicati<strong>on</strong>s of the <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s for63


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy were intensively discussed before the <strong>reform</strong>. Small<strong>municipal</strong>ities were widely c<strong>on</strong>sidered to be more democratic thanlarge <strong>on</strong>es, so worries of a democratic loss were widespread. Sec<strong>on</strong>d,inefficient service producti<strong>on</strong> in the small <strong>municipal</strong>ities was <strong>on</strong>eof the main arguments for the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. The argument wasdisputed at the time, but did amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s increase efficiency?Third, before 2007 <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> and regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s led separate livesin the Danish public sector, but the functi<strong>on</strong>al part of the 2007 <strong>reform</strong>forced them to work closely together in health care and specializedsocial services. How does <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>-regi<strong>on</strong>al coordinati<strong>on</strong> work inpractice?Local democracyThere is a l<strong>on</strong>g debate <strong>on</strong> the democratic pros and c<strong>on</strong>s of smallversus large <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Advocates of small units argue thatsmallness facilitates citizens’ participati<strong>on</strong> in politics, enhancestheir trust in their own political competence, and breeds civicc<strong>on</strong>sensus. It makes politics less abstract and increases politicians’resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to citizen views. It spreads political power, furthersc<strong>on</strong>trol over <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, increases political accountability andfacilitates exit-based empowerment of citizens. However, there arealso important democratic arguments against small jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s. Inlarge jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s, there is allegedly more diversity in beliefs andvalues, and politics becomes more competitive and professi<strong>on</strong>alized.Large units have greater system capacity and can supply a greaterrange of public services. They are less vulnerable to the influenceof <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> business and have more serious media coverage of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>politics. They also have more organizati<strong>on</strong>al activity and thus morecommunity groups, interest organizati<strong>on</strong>s and political parties (Dahland Tufte 1973; Treisman 2007).Before the <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s in 2007 the traditi<strong>on</strong>al viewin Denmark was that <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy is best served in small units.This was also the result reached by researchers of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracywho compared democracy in small and large <strong>municipal</strong>ities (e.g.Mouritzen, 1999). However, the most comprehensive review ofsize and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy before 2007 was published immediately64


Jens Blom-Hansenbefore the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s decisi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. This was areport by a group of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> researchers who investigatedthe relati<strong>on</strong>ship between the size of <strong>municipal</strong>ities and a number ofdemocratic features such as <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> identity, interest in and knowledgeof politics, participati<strong>on</strong>, trust, and satisfacti<strong>on</strong> (Kjær and Mouritzen,2003a). Their results showed that, measured according to thesestandards, there is no clear relati<strong>on</strong>ship between democracy andthe size of <strong>municipal</strong>ities. The researchers c<strong>on</strong>cluded that “Large<strong>municipal</strong>ities are not less democratic than small <strong>on</strong>es” (Kjær andMouritzen, 2003b: 193). Their report was published in the autumnof 2003, a few m<strong>on</strong>ths before the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s commissi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> theneed for a <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> completed its work. The researchers’c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> was immediately used as an argument that there areno democratic costs of amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. In this way an importantargument used by <strong>reform</strong> skeptics was wiped off the table.After the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s, it has become possible not <strong>on</strong>ly to comparedemocracy in small and large <strong>municipal</strong>ities in a cross-secti<strong>on</strong>alperspective. Now, democracy can be studied in <strong>municipal</strong>ities thathave underg<strong>on</strong>e a change from small to large units. So far, twostudies have been completed. The first is by Kjær and Olsen (2004,2006), who investigate the situati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the island of Bornholm wherefive <strong>municipal</strong>ities were amalgamated into <strong>on</strong>e in 2003. They find aremarkable decline in a number of indicators of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy, butalso some signs that the situati<strong>on</strong> may have improved somewhat aftera couple of years. The sec<strong>on</strong>d is by Lassen and Serritzlew (2011).They focus <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e democratic indicator, citizens’ political selfc<strong>on</strong>fidence(socalled internal political efficacy), and their studyincludes all Danish <strong>municipal</strong>ities before and after the 2007amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. They find that the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s led to a c<strong>on</strong>siderabledecline in political self-c<strong>on</strong>fidence. In sum, this evidence suggeststhat the Danish amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s came at a cost for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy.Efficiency in the <strong>municipal</strong> sectorFrom an ec<strong>on</strong>omic perspective, there are also important argumentsboth for and against small <strong>municipal</strong>ities. For many years ec<strong>on</strong>omistshave argued that small entities create the potential for welfare gains65


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>because public services can be better tailored to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> preferences(Oates 1972) or because citizens can move to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>ities that offer theideal tax-service package (Tiebout 1956). However, an equally l<strong>on</strong>glivedcounter-argument holds that large jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s are more costeffectivedue to ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in the producti<strong>on</strong> of many publicfuncti<strong>on</strong>s (Hirsch, 1959).The latter argument carried c<strong>on</strong>siderable weight in the Danishdebate before the 2007 amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. The general view was thatthe relati<strong>on</strong>ship between efficiency and <strong>municipal</strong>ity size was curvelinear.At the outset there are gains by going from small to somewhatlarger <strong>municipal</strong>ities, but gradually the gains flatten before theydisappear at a <strong>municipal</strong>ity size of about 30–40,000 inhabitants. Abovea certain threshold costs then start to increase again (Mouritzen, 1999,Houlberg, 2000). This view was also promoted by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’scommissi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the need for a <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>. But the view was notunchallenged. A study using different methods found no particularrelati<strong>on</strong>ship between size and efficiency (Blom-Hansen and Larsen,2005).All efficiency studies made before the 2007 amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s relied <strong>on</strong>cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al comparis<strong>on</strong>s of small and large <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Afterthe <strong>reform</strong> it has become possible to study how efficiency developsin <strong>municipal</strong>ities that undergo a change in size from small to large.So far, <strong>on</strong>ly two studies that both focus <strong>on</strong> administrative costs havebeen completed. The costs, of course, <strong>on</strong>ly c<strong>on</strong>stitute a minor shareof all <strong>municipal</strong> costs. But in most other policy areas scale effects in<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> are a questi<strong>on</strong> of the size of instituti<strong>on</strong>s, not the sizeof the <strong>municipal</strong>ity (Boyne, 1995). For instance, in the school areamost expenditure (wages to teachers, teaching material, buildings) isspent at the level of the individual schools, so the most relevant scalequesti<strong>on</strong> in this area is whether small schools are more expensivethan large <strong>on</strong>es. Therefore, scale effects at the <strong>municipal</strong> level aremost likely to be in the central administrative area. The first studyis c<strong>on</strong>ducted by the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> evaluati<strong>on</strong> institute, Krevi(Krevi, 2011), the sec<strong>on</strong>d by Blom-Hansen, Houlberg and Serritzlew(2012, see also Houlberg 2011). Both studies find that administrative66


Jens Blom-Hansencosts decline in <strong>municipal</strong>ities that undergo amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. Thefindings by Blom-Hansen, Houlberg and Serrritzlew are summarizedin Figure 1, which shows the isolated effect of amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s afterother relevant factors are taken into account (urbanizati<strong>on</strong>, changesin functi<strong>on</strong>al resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities, island status, social c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, fiscalpressure and decentralizati<strong>on</strong> of administrative staff). It shows thatuntil 2009 administrative costs increased in all <strong>municipal</strong>ities, butto a lesser extent in amalgamated <strong>on</strong>es. In 2010 administrativecosts declined in all <strong>municipal</strong>ities, most likely as a reacti<strong>on</strong> to thefiscal crisis. The gap that developed between amalgamated and n<strong>on</strong>amalgamated<strong>municipal</strong>ities in 2008 indicates that amalgamati<strong>on</strong>sindeed make efficiency gains possible.Figure 1Predicted administrative spending in Danish<strong>municipal</strong>ities 2005–2010 (DKK per capita)600058005600540052005000480046002005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010Not amalgamatedAmalgamatedNote: The figure shows the predicted administrative spending per capita for the amalgamatedand n<strong>on</strong>-amalgamated <strong>municipal</strong>ities. The predicted values are computed from a multivariateregressi<strong>on</strong> model. All c<strong>on</strong>trol variables are set to sample means. See Blom-Hansen, Houlbergand Serritzlew (2012) for further details.67


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>Local-regi<strong>on</strong>al coordinati<strong>on</strong> of health care and specialized socialserviceBefore the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> <strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, thecounties did not need to coordinate their activities to any great extent.The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s ambiti<strong>on</strong> when dividing tasks across tiers in thepublic sector was to create the clearest possible divisi<strong>on</strong> in order tomake both financial and political resp<strong>on</strong>sibility as clear as possible tocitizens. Of course, this ideal could not be completely achieved. Thehospital sector organized at the regi<strong>on</strong>al level has always had a needto cooperate with the old age care systems organized at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level;the primary school systems organized by the <strong>municipal</strong>ities havealways had to cooperate with the sec<strong>on</strong>dary educati<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>sorganized at the regi<strong>on</strong>al level; and the specialized social instituti<strong>on</strong>sorganized at the regi<strong>on</strong>al level have always had to cooperate with thegeneral social service system at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level. But the ambiti<strong>on</strong> wasto have clear and separate functi<strong>on</strong>al resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities.This ambiti<strong>on</strong> was given up in 2007 when the <strong>municipal</strong>ities tookover resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for all social services, also the hitherto specializedregi<strong>on</strong>al functi<strong>on</strong>s and part of the regi<strong>on</strong>al health care system. Inthese areas <strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s now have to cooperate andcoordinate their activities to an unprecedented extent.As noted above, in the area of specialized social services, the<strong>municipal</strong>ities were given the choice whether to take over the oldcounty instituti<strong>on</strong>s or let them be transferred to the new regi<strong>on</strong>s. Inthe end they took over almost all the counties’ old special instituti<strong>on</strong>s,and many <strong>municipal</strong>ities ended up with instituti<strong>on</strong>s for which theydid not have enough clients of their own. This created a market where<strong>municipal</strong>ities sell and buy places in specialized social instituti<strong>on</strong>s.As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, two coordinati<strong>on</strong> challenges have arisen. Not <strong>on</strong>lydo <strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s need to coordinate activity levels in the<strong>municipal</strong> instituti<strong>on</strong>s and the few remaining regi<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>s.They also need to coordinate activities in relati<strong>on</strong> to <strong>on</strong>e anothersince many <strong>municipal</strong>ities have clients placed in instituti<strong>on</strong>s run byother <strong>municipal</strong>ities.68


Jens Blom-HansenTo ease these coordinati<strong>on</strong> challenges, two adjustments have beenintroduced since 2007. First, the competence to refer clients toinstituti<strong>on</strong>s has been coupled with the financial resp<strong>on</strong>sibility. The2007 <strong>reform</strong> meant that the <strong>municipal</strong>ity of residence could decideactivity levels and treatments and have all costs reimbursed by thehome <strong>municipal</strong>ity. But in 2009 referral competence and financialresp<strong>on</strong>sibility were coupled so that the home <strong>municipal</strong>ity is resp<strong>on</strong>siblefor both decisi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> activity levels and costs. Expenditure and itsfinancing are thus decided by the same actor. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the systemof agreements between the regi<strong>on</strong>s and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities has beenchanged. The 2007 <strong>reform</strong> introduced a system according to which<strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s enter negotiated agreements <strong>on</strong> pricesand activity levels. This system was created with the expectati<strong>on</strong>that most of the specialized instituti<strong>on</strong>s would be run by the regi<strong>on</strong>s,which would then sell places to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities. The purpose ofthe agreements was therefore to c<strong>on</strong>trol the regi<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>s andtheir capacity, price policy and activity levels. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence,the regi<strong>on</strong>s were made resp<strong>on</strong>sible for organizing negotiati<strong>on</strong> of theagreements. But since the <strong>municipal</strong>ities chose to take over most ofthe regi<strong>on</strong>s’ instituti<strong>on</strong>s, selling and buying of places mostly takesplace between <strong>municipal</strong>ities, not between <strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s.In 2010 the system was therefore changed so that the agreementsfocused more <strong>on</strong> inter-<strong>municipal</strong> expenditure c<strong>on</strong>trol and professi<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment and less <strong>on</strong> <strong>municipal</strong>-regi<strong>on</strong>al relati<strong>on</strong>s. The formalresp<strong>on</strong>sibility for organizing negotiati<strong>on</strong> of the agreements was alsotransferred from the regi<strong>on</strong>s to the <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Gradually a systemhas been installed in which <strong>municipal</strong>ities are getting used to inter<strong>municipal</strong>coordinati<strong>on</strong> of capacity, prices, professi<strong>on</strong>al developmentand expenditure c<strong>on</strong>trol.In the health care area, the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> meant that the <strong>municipal</strong>itiestook over rehabilitati<strong>on</strong> of hospital patients, health preventi<strong>on</strong> andpromoti<strong>on</strong> of healthy life styles. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the <strong>municipal</strong>itiesbecame financially resp<strong>on</strong>sible for approximately 30 per cent ofthe costs of having their citizens treated at the regi<strong>on</strong>al hospitals.In the years after 2007 the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ main challenge has beento establish the organizati<strong>on</strong>al set-up for delivering their new health69


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>tasks. The challenge has been to create a structure that secures thatthe health area is coordinated with related <strong>municipal</strong> areas, especiallyold age care. The <strong>municipal</strong>ities have handled this challenge indifferent ways. Some establish new health departments within the<strong>municipal</strong> administrati<strong>on</strong>, others integrate the health area in existingdepartments, typically the social departments. Many <strong>municipal</strong>itiesalso establish health centers, where professi<strong>on</strong>als cooperate acrossadministrative and professi<strong>on</strong>al boundaries <strong>on</strong> preventi<strong>on</strong> andrehabilitati<strong>on</strong>. Another challenge is to establish good relati<strong>on</strong>s withthe regi<strong>on</strong>s. This is d<strong>on</strong>e by way of new agreements which the<strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s have to make <strong>on</strong> activity levels, divisi<strong>on</strong>of work, planning of discharges, etc. But the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> hasalso encouraged good <strong>municipal</strong>-regi<strong>on</strong>al relati<strong>on</strong>s by offering grantsfor well-planned patient processes across <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> boundaries.Finally, in to increase the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ financial incentive to deliverefficient health services their co-financing of regi<strong>on</strong>al hospital costswas raised from 30 to 34 per cent in 2010.The new need to coordinate activities regi<strong>on</strong>ally am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>municipal</strong>itiesand between <strong>municipal</strong>ities and the regi<strong>on</strong> has led to a new regi<strong>on</strong>alcoordinati<strong>on</strong> game in which actors invest c<strong>on</strong>siderable resources informing alliances in order to pursue their interests. The <strong>municipal</strong>ities’nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong> has established regi<strong>on</strong>al offices that support the<strong>municipal</strong>ities’ regi<strong>on</strong>al interacti<strong>on</strong>s with their regi<strong>on</strong>. This is used asa forum by the <strong>municipal</strong>ities to coordinate negotiati<strong>on</strong> tactics vis-àvisthe regi<strong>on</strong>. But <strong>municipal</strong>ities are also sometimes pitted againsteach other. In specialized social services, some <strong>municipal</strong>ities sellplaces while others buy them. In the health area, <strong>municipal</strong>ities mayhave diverging interests in their interacti<strong>on</strong>s with the regi<strong>on</strong>, forexample in relati<strong>on</strong> to the locati<strong>on</strong> of new hospitals or closing downexisting <strong>on</strong>es. A new game of inter-<strong>municipal</strong> alliance-building istherefore developing in both areas (Heeager, 2012).70


Jens Blom-Hansen3.7 Challenges since 2007: C<strong>on</strong>trolling <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>expenditureC<strong>on</strong>trolling the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ expenditure has been the mainchallenge in the years after the 2007 <strong>reform</strong>; partly because <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>expenditure rose dramatically in the first years after the <strong>reform</strong>, partlybecause the financial crisis from 2009 made c<strong>on</strong>trol more salient forthe central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> has met this challenge byintroducing ever tighter c<strong>on</strong>trol of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic dispositi<strong>on</strong>s.C<strong>on</strong>trolling expenditure in the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> sector is no newchallenge for the Danish central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Ever since the 1970<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s have been resp<strong>on</strong>sible for alarge share of the Danish public budget. Macroec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>trol hastherefore for a l<strong>on</strong>g time been difficult without some coordinati<strong>on</strong>of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic dispositi<strong>on</strong>s with the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’smacroec<strong>on</strong>omic policy goals. The Danish soluti<strong>on</strong> to this challengehas been a system of annual negotiati<strong>on</strong>s and agreements betweenthe central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>(Kommunernes Landsforening) and the regi<strong>on</strong>s’ nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>(Amtsrådsforeningen before 2007, Danske Regi<strong>on</strong>er after 2007), theso called budgetary cooperati<strong>on</strong> between central, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> and regi<strong>on</strong>al<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The annual agreements c<strong>on</strong>tain guidelines for the overallexpenditure and taxati<strong>on</strong> level in the <strong>municipal</strong> and regi<strong>on</strong>al sector.During the <strong>reform</strong> years 2004–2007 this negotiati<strong>on</strong> system wasformally kept intact, but in reality c<strong>on</strong>trol of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditurewas achieved by strict legal regulati<strong>on</strong> by the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.To counter a flurry of unsound ec<strong>on</strong>omic dispositi<strong>on</strong>s before theamalgamati<strong>on</strong>s, the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> introduced a number ofc<strong>on</strong>trol measures, including central approval systems for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>investments, obligatory saving schemes for socalled surplusliquid means (i.e., liquid means above a certain amount), approvalsystems for supplementary appropriati<strong>on</strong>s, fees <strong>on</strong> supplementaryappropriati<strong>on</strong>s, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax freezes. It is not easy to evaluate howsuccessful these measures were. It is unquesti<strong>on</strong>able that some71


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>‘spending before closing time’ took place (Blom-Hansen, 2010), butthis would probably have been more widespread in the absence of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s counter measures.The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s strict course was widely accepted by the<strong>municipal</strong>ities and their nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>. But the implicitc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> was that the c<strong>on</strong>trols were loosened <strong>on</strong>ce the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>swere in place. In 2007, the first year after the <strong>reform</strong>, the central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> kept the tight regime in place and dictated the tax ratesof all the new <strong>municipal</strong>ities. But then all c<strong>on</strong>trols were lifted, and inthe spring of 2007 negotiati<strong>on</strong>s between the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> andthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> associati<strong>on</strong> were started anew. The negotiati<strong>on</strong>sled to a traditi<strong>on</strong>al and relatively gentle agreement, which made roomfor some increase in both expenditure and taxati<strong>on</strong>. Apparently, thesystem was back to normal.But when the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ 2008 budgets were completedsome m<strong>on</strong>ths afterwards, it became clear that the agreement wasbroken to an unprecedented extent. Municipal expenditure exceededthe agreed guideline by more than 1 billi<strong>on</strong> DKK, and taxati<strong>on</strong>exceeded the agreement by more than 1.5 billi<strong>on</strong> DKK. The breachof the agreement had historical dimensi<strong>on</strong>s, and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong> gave up trying to explain it away or pleading fora triviality limit. Initially the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> did not react because thesituati<strong>on</strong> coincided with the nati<strong>on</strong>al electi<strong>on</strong> in the autumn of 2007.But in the spring of 2008 the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> introduced the so-calledsancti<strong>on</strong> legislati<strong>on</strong>, which was gradually tightened the followingyears. The sancti<strong>on</strong> laws, enacted with the help of the right-wingDanish People’s Party, aimed at both expenditure and taxati<strong>on</strong> in the<strong>municipal</strong>ities. On the expenditure side, a rule was introduced thatallows the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> to withhold 1 billi<strong>on</strong> DKK from thegeneral block grant if <strong>municipal</strong> budgets do not respect the agreedexpenditure guidelines. This became known as the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al blockgrant. On the taxati<strong>on</strong> side, sancti<strong>on</strong>s for tax rises were introduced. If<strong>municipal</strong> budgets include tax rises exceeding the agreed guidelines,a corresp<strong>on</strong>ding cut in the general block grant is implemented. Therevenue effect of the tax rise is thus neutralized.72


Jens Blom-HansenWhile the new sancti<strong>on</strong> system <strong>on</strong> the expenditure side – that is, thepotential withholding of the general block grant – was collective, thetax sancti<strong>on</strong>s combined individual and collective elements. In the firstyear 75 per cent of the revenue generated by a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax increase is offsetby a corresp<strong>on</strong>ding cut in the individual <strong>municipal</strong>ity’s grant from thecentral <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The remaining 25 per cent is neutralized by a cutin the general block grant, which is allocated am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>municipal</strong>itiesin proporti<strong>on</strong> to jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> size. The individual sancti<strong>on</strong> is graduallyphased out, with a corresp<strong>on</strong>ding increase in the collective element,cf. Table 6. As is also evident from this table, the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>strengthened the individual element in 2010 (effective 2011) makingit even more unattractive, from the perspective of the individual<strong>municipal</strong>ity, to increase <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxes as seen.Table 6Municipal tax limitati<strong>on</strong>s in DenmarkIndividual sancti<strong>on</strong> (%) Collective sancti<strong>on</strong> (%)Act 477/2008 Year 1: 75 Year 1: 25(effective from 2009) Year 2: 50 Year 2: 50Year 3-: 0 Year 3-: 100Act 709/2010 Year 1: 75 Year 1: 25(effective from 2011) Year 2: 50 Year 2: 50Year 3: 50 Year 3: 50Year 4: 25 Year 4: 75Year 5-: 0 Year 5-: 100The sancti<strong>on</strong>s were effective from 2009, and they worked. In thespring of 2008 an agreement was, as usual, negotiated between the<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>. Again, itc<strong>on</strong>tained guidelines <strong>on</strong> <strong>municipal</strong> expenditure and tax levels in thecoming year. When the <strong>municipal</strong> 2009 budgets were subsequentlycompleted, they respected the guidelines. This fact is a direct resultof the sancti<strong>on</strong> system which focused <strong>on</strong> the <strong>municipal</strong> budgets. But<strong>on</strong>e and a half years later, the drawback of focusing exclusively <strong>on</strong>73


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>budgets became clear. The accounts showed that the budgets wereexceeded dramatically – by a full 5 billi<strong>on</strong> DKK. Budget overrunsof this magnitude are unprecedented. For two c<strong>on</strong>secutive years,the <strong>municipal</strong>ities had now had remarkable difficulties c<strong>on</strong>trollingexpenditure. Problems were not least evident in the new areas whichthe <strong>municipal</strong>ities had taken over in the 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>. Halfof the 2009 budget overrun was in specialized social services, whichthe <strong>municipal</strong>ities had taken over from the old counties.The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s reacti<strong>on</strong> was to tighten the screws in the sancti<strong>on</strong>system. Again this was d<strong>on</strong>e with the help of the Danish People’sParty. On the taxati<strong>on</strong> side, the individual element of the sancti<strong>on</strong>swas increased, cf. Table 6. On the expenditure side, the system ofc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al block grants was expanded. First, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> raisedthe c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al element from 1 to 3 billi<strong>on</strong> DKK in case <strong>municipal</strong>budgets did not respect the guidelines in the annual agreement.Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the system was extended to include accounts. If accountsdo not respect the budgets, the general block grant is reducedcorresp<strong>on</strong>dingly, but within a limit of 3 billi<strong>on</strong> DKK.The sancti<strong>on</strong> system has been even further refined after this change.In 2011, the sancti<strong>on</strong> for budget overruns was changed from a purelycollective sancti<strong>on</strong> to <strong>on</strong>e including both individual and collectiveelements. According to this change, in case of budget overruns, 60per cent of the overruns are neutralized individually, while <strong>on</strong>ly 40per cent are collective.The screws were further tightened in the spring of 2012 inc<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong> with the introducti<strong>on</strong> of a general Danish budget law.The law implements the EU’s financial pact in Denmark, but the<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> used the occasi<strong>on</strong> to increase <strong>municipal</strong> expenditurec<strong>on</strong>trol even further. Two new elements were added to the sancti<strong>on</strong>system. First, the combinati<strong>on</strong> of individual and collective elementsin the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al block grant system was extended. From now <strong>on</strong>,it not <strong>on</strong>ly holds in relati<strong>on</strong> to accounts exceeding budgets, but alsoto budgets exceeding the agreed guidelines. Again, 60 per cent areneutralized individually, while 40 per cent are collective. Sec<strong>on</strong>d,74


Jens Blom-Hansenthe requirement to balance budgets was tightened. It has alwaysbeen obligatory for Danish <strong>municipal</strong>ities to balance their budgets,but the exact nature of the requirement has been relatively vague.For instance, it includes loans. Now, the requirement to balancebudgets is supplemented with a stipulati<strong>on</strong> that focuses exclusively<strong>on</strong> current expenditure and income and requires not <strong>on</strong>ly a balance,but a surplus 5 .Table 7The sancti<strong>on</strong> system in relati<strong>on</strong> to <strong>municipal</strong> taxati<strong>on</strong>and expenditureTaxati<strong>on</strong> sancti<strong>on</strong>s :Sancti<strong>on</strong> for tax rises in violati<strong>on</strong> ofguidelines in agreement between the<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>alassociati<strong>on</strong> (revenue neutralized by cuts inblock grant)Expenditure sancti<strong>on</strong>s :Budgets:Sancti<strong>on</strong> for expenditure level exceedingguidelines in agreement between the<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities’ nati<strong>on</strong>alassociati<strong>on</strong> (c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al blockgrant)Accounts:Sancti<strong>on</strong> for accounts exceeding budgets(c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al blockgrant)Requirement to balance the budget :2009 2010 2011 2012 2013+ + ++ ++ +++ + ++ ++ +++- - + + ++Balanced budget + + + + ++Note: ‘+’ indicates that the sancti<strong>on</strong> is in place. Increasing numbers of ‘+’ indicates atightening of the sancti<strong>on</strong>5 The new balance rules will be specified in detail in an executive decree from the<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. The budget law, enacted in June 2012, <strong>on</strong>ly includes a delegati<strong>on</strong> provisi<strong>on</strong> tothis effect.75


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>In sum, over the years 2008–2012 the Danish central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>has introduced and gradually refined a system of central c<strong>on</strong>trol of<strong>municipal</strong> expenditure and taxati<strong>on</strong> that c<strong>on</strong>stitutes a remarkablebreak with the Danish traditi<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> aut<strong>on</strong>omy. It has been asilent revoluti<strong>on</strong> that has g<strong>on</strong>e unnoticed by the media as well asthe populati<strong>on</strong>. It has also been an area of parliamentary c<strong>on</strong>sensus.Until the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> change in 2011 all changes were introducedby the Liberal-C<strong>on</strong>servative <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> with the help of the rightwingDanish People’s Party. This might indicate that the left wing ofthe Danish parliament disagreed with the sancti<strong>on</strong> system. However,when the left wing <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> led by the Social Democratic Partytook over in 2011, it did not roll back the system. On the c<strong>on</strong>trary,the screws in the system were tightened even further. The gradualintroducti<strong>on</strong> of the sancti<strong>on</strong> system is summarized in Table 7.The sancti<strong>on</strong> system works. In both 2010 and 2011 the agreementswere kept, both in the <strong>municipal</strong> budgets and the accounts. In additi<strong>on</strong>,the sancti<strong>on</strong> system has enabled the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> to actively use<strong>municipal</strong> budgets to help cut down public expenditure in the wakeof the financial crisis beginning in 2009. Figure 2 shows <strong>municipal</strong>wage expenditure in the years 2007–2012, according to both budgetsand accounts. Wages are the most direct measure of c<strong>on</strong>trollableexpenditure in the <strong>municipal</strong> sector so the figure indicates the result ofgeneral expenditure c<strong>on</strong>trol measures. The dramatic increase in 2008and 2009 is evident from the figure. It is also evident that accountsexceed budgets, especially in 2009. However, 2009 represents apeak. From then <strong>on</strong> the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> has not <strong>on</strong>ly succeededin bringing down <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditure, but also in aligning budgets andaccounts. Expenditure has been reduced across the board in <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>budgets. So far, reducti<strong>on</strong>s have not led to service or quality reducti<strong>on</strong>sin <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services that have generated widespread <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> protests. In theservice areas cuts have been facilitated by the closure and mergingof service providing instituti<strong>on</strong>s, especially in the school area wherea l<strong>on</strong>g term trend to close and merge schools has been accelerated inthe past 4–5 years (Bækgaard, 2010).76


Jens Blom-HansenFigure 2 Municipalities’ expenditure <strong>on</strong> wages 2007–2012(thousand DKK, 2012 price level)1740000001720000001700000001680000001660000001640000001620000001600000001580000001560000001540000002007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012Wages (budget)Wages (accounts)Source: Statistics DenmarkDeflator: Municipal price and wage factor3.8 New <strong>reform</strong>s? The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s 2013 evaluati<strong>on</strong>of the 2007 <strong>reform</strong>The Danish 2007 <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong> is now five years old. As is evidentfrom the previous secti<strong>on</strong>s, there have been various adjustmentssince 2007, but no major changes. Speculati<strong>on</strong>s of new <strong>reform</strong>shave mostly focused <strong>on</strong> the regi<strong>on</strong>s. Their existence has never beencompletely secured or accepted. Indeed, before 2007 the old countieswere often threatened with abolishment. To make matters worse, anevaluati<strong>on</strong> in 2010 showed that the political system in the regi<strong>on</strong>sis organized in a way that creates c<strong>on</strong>siderable frustrati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>gregi<strong>on</strong>al politicians (Mouritzen, 2010). The regi<strong>on</strong>s are not allowedto establish permanent committees under the regi<strong>on</strong>al councils. This77


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>c<strong>on</strong>centrates power in the hands of the regi<strong>on</strong>al chairman and theregi<strong>on</strong>al administrative system. Influence for ordinary members ofthe regi<strong>on</strong>al council is reduced, which again makes it harder to recruitcandidates for regi<strong>on</strong>al electi<strong>on</strong>s.Immediately before the nati<strong>on</strong>al electi<strong>on</strong>s in 2011 the Liberal-C<strong>on</strong>servative <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> negotiated the future of the regi<strong>on</strong>s withits support party, the Danish People’s Party, and agreed to abolishthe regi<strong>on</strong>s and transfer the hospitals to the central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>(Regeringen og Dansk Folkeparti 2011). It was a short agreement <strong>on</strong>principles that would be specified in detail <strong>on</strong> the basis of subsequentin-depth inquiry by <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> working groups. But the agreementincreased the salience of the issue in the ensuing electi<strong>on</strong> campaign.The parties c<strong>on</strong>stituting the alternative to the Liberal-C<strong>on</strong>servative<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> promised not to abolish the counties if they w<strong>on</strong> theelecti<strong>on</strong>s, but instead to evaluate the whole 2007 <strong>reform</strong> complex.Having w<strong>on</strong> the electi<strong>on</strong>s, the new <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> under SocialDemocratic leadership included in its detailed <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> platforman evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the divisi<strong>on</strong> of functi<strong>on</strong>s between regi<strong>on</strong>s and<strong>municipal</strong>ities (Regeringen, 2011: 64). The evaluati<strong>on</strong> would focus<strong>on</strong> the part of the 2007 <strong>reform</strong> dealing with functi<strong>on</strong>s, but wouldnot evaluate the existence of the regi<strong>on</strong>s or the <strong>municipal</strong>amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s. It would not evaluate the basic distributi<strong>on</strong> offuncti<strong>on</strong>s across tiers, but focus <strong>on</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> problems in areasof divided resp<strong>on</strong>sibility. In other words, the evaluati<strong>on</strong> was goodnews for the regi<strong>on</strong>s whose existence and functi<strong>on</strong>al resp<strong>on</strong>sibilitieswere not put at risk. The evaluati<strong>on</strong> was initiated in February 2012and organized under the Ministry of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Interior Affairs.Four working groups with representatives from the <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>ministries and the associati<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>municipal</strong>ities and regi<strong>on</strong>s, but nooutside experts, will investigate the distributi<strong>on</strong> of functi<strong>on</strong>s betweenthe central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, the regi<strong>on</strong>s and the <strong>municipal</strong>ities in thefollowing areas: Health care, envir<strong>on</strong>mental protecti<strong>on</strong>, regi<strong>on</strong>aldevelopment, and specialized social service. The working groups areto complete their work in the autumn of 2012. The <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s goalis then to draw the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s from the evaluati<strong>on</strong> in the spring of2013.78


Jens Blom-HansenReferencesBlom-Hansen, Jens (2010): Municipal Amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s and Comm<strong>on</strong> PoolProblems: The Danish Local Government Reform in 2007, ScandinavianPolitical Studies 33: 51–73.Blom-Hansen, Jens – Larsen, Brian (2005): Jo større, jo dyrere. En ny belysning afskalaeffekter i den kommunale administrati<strong>on</strong>, Nordisk Administrativt Tidsskrift86: 5–27.Blom-Hansen, Jens – Heeager, Anne (2010): Denmark: Between Local Democracyand Implementing Agency of the Welfare State, pp. 221-241, in Loughlin,John – Hendriks, Frank – Lidström, Anders (eds.) The Oxford Handbook ofLocal and Regi<strong>on</strong>al Democracy in Europe, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Blom-Hansen, Jens – Ibsen, Marius – Juul, Thorkil – Mouritzen, Poul Erik (2012):Fra sogn til velfærdsproducent. Kommunestyret gennem fire årtier, Odense,Syddansk Universitetsforlag.Blom-Hansen, Jens – Houlberg, Kurt – Serritzlew, Søren (2012): Size, Democracy,and the Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Costs of Running the Political System, Aarhus University,Department of Political Science.Blöndal, J<strong>on</strong> R. (2003): Accrual Accounting and Budgeting: Key Issues and RecentDevelopments, OECD Journal <strong>on</strong> Budgeting 3: 43–59.Boyne, George A. (1995): Populati<strong>on</strong> Size and Ec<strong>on</strong>omies of Scale in LocalGovernment, Policy and Politics 23: 213–222.Bundsgaard, Inge (2000): Statslig lokalforvaltning og kommunalt selvstyre, pp.841–91 in Dansk forvaltningshistorie I: Fra middelalderen til 1901, Copenhagen:Jurist- og Øk<strong>on</strong>omforbundets Forlag.Bækgaard, Martin (2010): Skolelukninger i kommunal<strong>reform</strong>ens skygge? Enanalyse af kommunal<strong>reform</strong>ens policy-k<strong>on</strong>sekvenser, Tidsskriftet Politik 13:28–38.Christiansen, Peter Munk – Klitgaard, Michael Baggesen (2008): Den utænkelige<strong>reform</strong>, Struktur<strong>reform</strong>ens tilblivelse 2002–2005, Odense: SyddanskUniversitetsforlag.Dahl, Robert A. – Tufte, Edward R. (1973): Size and Democracy, Stanford:Stanford University Press.Dedenroth-Schou, Birgitte – Dyrbye, Holger – Thomsen, Jørgen (1991): Rammernefor kommunestyret 1867/68–1970, pp. <str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>–141, in Boje, Per – Dedenroth-Schou,79


Local Government in Denmark and the 2007<strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>Birgitte –Jespersen, Knud J. V. –Thomsen, Jørgen (eds.) Folkestyre i by og påland, Danske kommuner gennem 150 år, Copenhagen, Poul Kristensens Forlag.Finansministeriet (2003): Omkostninger og effektivitet i staten, København.Heeager, Anne (2012): Kommuner som interessevaretager. Et studie af danskekommuners brug af alliancer i den regi<strong>on</strong>ale interessevaretagelse, Aarhus,Politica.Hirsch, Werner Z. (1959): Expenditure Implicati<strong>on</strong>s of Metropolitan Growth andC<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong>, Review of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Statistics 41: 232–241.Houlberg, Kurt (2000): Kommunale stordriftsfordele – hvor finder vi dem, og hvorstore er de?, Copenhagen, AKF forlaget.Houlberg, Kurt (2011): Administrative stordriftsfordele ved kommunal<strong>reform</strong>eni Danmark, Sandede eller tilsandede, Scandinavian Journal of PublicAdministrati<strong>on</strong>, 15(1): 41–<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Indenrigs- og Sundhedsministerens rådgivende udvalg (2003): Sundhedsvæsenetsorganisering – sygehuse, incitamenter, amter og alternativer, Copenhagen.Ingvartsen, Oluf – Mikkelsen, Palle (1991): Hovedtræk, vurdering ogfremtidsperspektiver, Volume 6 in Kommunal<strong>reform</strong>en i Danmark, Copenhagen,Kommuneinformati<strong>on</strong>.Kjellberg, Francesco (1995): The Changing Values of Local Government, Annalsof the American Academy of Political and Social Science 540: 40–50.Kjær, Ulrik – Mouritzen, Poul Erik (eds.) (2003a): Kommunestørrelse og lokaltdemokrati, Syddansk Universitetsforlag.Kjær, Ulrik – Mouritzen, Poul Erik (2003b): K<strong>on</strong>klusi<strong>on</strong>, pp. 193-207, in UlrikKjær and Poul Erik Mouritzen (eds.) Kommunestørrelse og lokalt demokrati,Syddansk Universitetsforlag.Kjær, Ulrik – Olsen, Leif (2004): Kommunesammenlægningens første år bedømtaf borgerne på Bornholm, København, AKF forlaget.Kjær, Ulrik – Olsen, Leif (2006): Bornholmerne og demokratiet efterkommunesammenlægningen, AKF forlaget.Krevi (2011): Kommunernes administrative ressourceforbrug – udviklingen 2006–2010, Aarhus.Lassen, David Dreyer – Serritzlew, Søren (2011): Jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> Size and LocalDemocracy: Evidence <strong>on</strong> Internal Political Efficacy from Large-scale MunicipalReform, American Political Science Review 105: 238–258.80


Jens Blom-HansenLF 191/2012. Lovforslag nr. L 191 fremsat den 22. maj 2012 af øk<strong>on</strong>omi- ogindenrigsministeren (Margrethe Vestager) til Lov om ændring af lov om kommunaludligning og generelle tilskud til kommuner (justeringer af udligningssystemet).Available at www.ft.dk.Mouritzen, Poul Erik (1999): De små kommuner. De ikk’ så ringe endda?,Copenhagen, AKF Forlaget.Mouritzen, Poul Erik (ed.) (2010): Opfundet til lejligheden? Evaluering afregi<strong>on</strong>ernes politiske sty<strong>reform</strong>, Syddansk universitetsforlag.Oates, Wallace E. (1972): Fiscal Federalism, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Page, Edward C. (1991): Localism and Centralism in Europe, Oxford UniversityPress.Pedersen, Kjeld Møller (2005): Kommunal medfinansiering af sundhedsvæsenet.En idé på sandgrund?, Syddansk Universitetsforlag.Regeringen (2004): Aftale om struktur<strong>reform</strong>, Juni 2004, København.Regeringen (2011): Et Danmark, der står sammen, Government platform, October2011. Available at www.stm.dk.Regeringen og Dansk Folkeparti (2011): Politisk forståelse om en ny organiseringaf sundhedsområdet og øvrige regi<strong>on</strong>ale områder, 19. august 2011. Offentliggjortpå www.fm.dk.Skjæveland, Asbjørn – Serritzlew, Søren – Blom-Hansen, Jens (2007): Theoriesof Coaliti<strong>on</strong> Formati<strong>on</strong>: An Empirical Test Using Data from Danish LocalGovernment, European Journal of Political Research 46: 721–45.Strukturkommissi<strong>on</strong>en (2004): Strukturkommissi<strong>on</strong>ens betænkning, Betænkningnr. 1434, København.Tiebout, Charles M. (1956): A Pure Theory of Local Expenditure, Journal ofPolitical Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 64: 416–424.Treisman, Daniel (2007): The Architecture of Government, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Rethinking</str<strong>on</strong>g> PoliticalDecentralizati<strong>on</strong>, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.81


Chapter 4Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?Enid SlackInstitute <strong>on</strong> Municipal Finance and GovernanceMunk School of Global AffairsUniversity of Tor<strong>on</strong>toRichard M. BirdRotman School of ManagementInstitute for Municipal Governance and FinanceUniversity of Tor<strong>on</strong>toThe quantity and quality of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public services and the efficiencywith which they are delivered in a metropolitan area depend, to ac<strong>on</strong>siderable extent, <strong>on</strong> how its governance instituti<strong>on</strong>s – especially itsformal <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al structures – functi<strong>on</strong>. Governance determineshow efficiently costs are shared throughout the metropolitan area aswell as how service delivery is coordinated across <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>boundaries, how effectively <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents and businesses can access<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s and influence their decisi<strong>on</strong>s, and how accountable <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are to their citizens and how resp<strong>on</strong>sive they are to theirdemands. And of course all these relati<strong>on</strong>ships themselves affect boththe nature and operati<strong>on</strong> of governance instituti<strong>on</strong>s.What is the appropriate governance structure for metropolitan areas?How can services which extend bey<strong>on</strong>d <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> boundariesbe delivered and financed? Are some <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s even withinmetropolitan areas too small to be able to deliver and finance important83


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?services? 1 How can service delivery be coordinated when differentjurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s are involved? Should large cities be governed by a singletier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> or are some cities simply too large and complex forsuch an arrangement? How well does voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s within a metropolitan area work?This paper reviews different ways in which the formal governanceof metropolitan areas may be restructured, focusing in particular <strong>on</strong><strong>municipal</strong> mergers with the case of Tor<strong>on</strong>to, Canada, as an example.Secti<strong>on</strong> 4.1 begins by setting out some criteria that may be usedto evaluate mergers and other ways of restructuring metropolitangovernance. Secti<strong>on</strong> 4.2 reviews the advantages and disadvantagesof <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> mergers in particular, while Secti<strong>on</strong> 4.3 c<strong>on</strong>siders suchalternatives to mergers as two-tier structures, voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong>,and special districts. Secti<strong>on</strong> 4.4 discusses in some detail thec<strong>on</strong>voluted history of amalgamati<strong>on</strong> in Tor<strong>on</strong>to and evaluates whatit has achieved. Secti<strong>on</strong> 4.5 c<strong>on</strong>cludes with a brief c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> ofwhether the Tor<strong>on</strong>to experience suggests any less<strong>on</strong>s for Finnishmetropolitan areas.4.1 Criteria for evaluating <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> governancestructuresA comm<strong>on</strong> reas<strong>on</strong> for c<strong>on</strong>sidering <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong> isto improve the effectiveness and efficiency with which <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s deliver services. In Finland, this c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> seemsnot <strong>on</strong>ly to have been the main reas<strong>on</strong> for the c<strong>on</strong>siderable number of<strong>municipal</strong> mergers that have taken place in recent years (Associati<strong>on</strong>2011) but also to be the primary driver behind the intenti<strong>on</strong> to movestill further in this directi<strong>on</strong> (Moisio 2011a). Municipal amalgamati<strong>on</strong>is seen primarily as a way to ensure that Finnish <strong>municipal</strong>ities will besufficiently large to be financially and technically capable of ensuringeffective, efficient and sustainable provisi<strong>on</strong> of the extensive array ofsocial services with which they are charged. In more general terms,1 We do not discuss in this paper the quite different problems that may arise infinancing public services in small and remote communities (Kitchen and Slack 2006).84


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdthe intenti<strong>on</strong> appears to be to ensure that <strong>municipal</strong>ities will be ablenot <strong>on</strong>ly to reap ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale but also to coordinate servicedelivery over their entire (enlarged) territory as well as to share costsequitably and to reduce (even eliminate) spillovers of service deliveryacross <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> boundaries.These objectives are certainly legitimate, and may indeed suggest thatlarger c<strong>on</strong>solidated <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> units would produce better outcomesthan small separate <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Most countries have dealt withsuch issues ‘vertically’ – by superimposing such units ‘<strong>on</strong> top of’existing units or by shifting services ‘upwards’ to higher levels –rather than ‘horiz<strong>on</strong>tally’, simply by enlarging <strong>municipal</strong> boundaries.One reas<strong>on</strong> such alternative approaches are followed is becauserelatively small <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> units are c<strong>on</strong>sidered to play an importantrole in ensuring adequate <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘voice’ and accountability. Theseissues have mainly been discussed in other countries with respect tothe governance of metropolitan regi<strong>on</strong>s although no ‘<strong>on</strong>e size fits all’model has emerged from this discussi<strong>on</strong> (Bird and Slack 2008). Asis often the case with instituti<strong>on</strong>al design, while the questi<strong>on</strong>s to bedealt with seem universal, the answers are invariably highly c<strong>on</strong>textspecific,and policy choices are seldom clear cut (Stren and Camer<strong>on</strong>2005).The ‘subsidiarity principle,’ for example, suggests that the efficientprovisi<strong>on</strong> of services requires decisi<strong>on</strong>-making to be carried out bythe level of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> that is closest to the individual citizen so thatresources will be allocated with the greatest efficiency, accountability,and resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. 2 When there are <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> differences in tastes andcosts, there are clear efficiency gains from delivering services in asdecentralized a fashi<strong>on</strong> as possible. Smaller, fragmented generalpurpose<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> units may also stimulate competiti<strong>on</strong> between<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s for mobile residents and tax bases that will inducethem to offer the best possible mix of taxes and services (Klink2 The subsidiarity principle, included in the Treaty of the European Uni<strong>on</strong> in 1992in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the divisi<strong>on</strong> of powers and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities between European <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>albodies and their member countries, has been applied to the role and structure of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>at all levels (Barnett 1997).85


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?2008). 3 Access and accountability – both of which depend to ac<strong>on</strong>siderable degree up<strong>on</strong> the extent to which citizens have access to<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> through public meetings, hearings, electi<strong>on</strong>s, anddirect c<strong>on</strong>tacts with officials – also appear easier to achieve when<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> units are smaller and more fragmented (Faguet2004, 2011). The larger the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, the more likely it isthat special interest groups will dominate citizen participati<strong>on</strong> (Bish2001).On the other hand, a larger and more c<strong>on</strong>solidated <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>structure may be able to take advantage of ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in serviceprovisi<strong>on</strong> as well as savings in administrative overhead, thus reapinglower per unit costs as the amount of the service delivered increases. 4The existence of externalities (inter-jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>al spillovers) mayrequire a larger <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> to ensure that all benefitsof a particular public service are enjoyed within the boundaries ofthat jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>. A larger <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> with a str<strong>on</strong>geradministrative and fiscal base may also help all communities in agiven area – both those with high needs and a small tax base and thosewith low needs and a small tax base – to provide an adequate level ofservice. In ec<strong>on</strong>omic (and fiscal) terms, the choice of an appropriategovernance structure for a metropolitan area depends up<strong>on</strong> how <strong>on</strong>eweighs these c<strong>on</strong>flicting c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s – efficiency, resp<strong>on</strong>siveness,and accountability versus ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale, externalities, and thecapacity to deliver and coordinate services.4.2 To merge or not to mergeIn a <strong>on</strong>e-tier structure, <strong>on</strong>e political body makes taxing andspending decisi<strong>on</strong>s for the metropolitan area. 5 Even within a unified3 Such competiti<strong>on</strong> is perhaps especially important with respect to the adaptabilitythat is increasingly a critical aspect of effective <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> governance in a global ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Asnoted by Berry (2009), however, fragmenting governance am<strong>on</strong>g special-purpose districts isunlikely to have any beneficial competitive effects.4 On the other hand, some evidence suggests that costs are higher for larger<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> units because of “bureaucratic c<strong>on</strong>gesti<strong>on</strong>” (Boyne 1992, 336) and other factors.Ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale are discussed further below.5 Large, c<strong>on</strong>solidated single-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are generally formed by either86


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdmetropolitan <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, however, services need not be provideduniformly throughout the metropolitan area. When a <strong>on</strong>e-tier<strong>municipal</strong>ity is created by amalgamating <strong>municipal</strong>ities, sometimesdifferential services and service levels existing prior to the creati<strong>on</strong>of the unified <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> persist. For example, rural residents do notnecessarily receive all of the services available to urban residents.Presumably, if <strong>on</strong>e reas<strong>on</strong> for amalgamati<strong>on</strong> is to create a jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>that encompasses the entire city-regi<strong>on</strong>, such differences in servicedelivery and tax rates should not be maintained bey<strong>on</strong>d a shorttransiti<strong>on</strong> period.C<strong>on</strong>solidated <strong>on</strong>e-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s were str<strong>on</strong>gly favoured in theseminal study by Bahl and Linn (1992) as providing greater fiscalcapacity, better service coordinati<strong>on</strong>, clearer accountability, morestreamlined decisi<strong>on</strong>-making, and greater efficiency. The largertaxable capacity of a c<strong>on</strong>solidated <strong>on</strong>e-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> increasesits ability to borrow and to recover capital and operating costs fromuser fees. Services may be funded more fairly because there is awider tax base for sharing the costs of services that benefit taxpayersacross the regi<strong>on</strong>. Large <strong>on</strong>e-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s can take advantage ofec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in service provisi<strong>on</strong>. Municipal amalgamati<strong>on</strong>smay internalize externalities: for example, rural residents outside ofthe original <strong>municipal</strong> boundary now have to pay for urban servicesthat they use. 6How successful c<strong>on</strong>solidated <strong>on</strong>e-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s have been inpractice at achieving accountability is a matter of debate. A largescale<strong>on</strong>e-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> may reduce access and accountabilitybecause the jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> becomes too large and bureaucratic. Toovercome this problem, in some cases community committees haveamalgamati<strong>on</strong> (the merger of two or more geographically c<strong>on</strong>tiguous lower-tier<strong>municipal</strong>ities) or annexati<strong>on</strong> (the appropriati<strong>on</strong> of a porti<strong>on</strong> of a <strong>municipal</strong>ity by an adjacent<strong>municipal</strong>ity).6 Redrawing boundaries is <strong>on</strong>ly a first step in linking taxes to service benefits byensuring that the beneficiaries are located within the jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> providing the services. Thecritical sec<strong>on</strong>d step is to identify the benefits received by residents and to tax (or charge)them accordingly. For example, while it is fair and efficient to charge rural residents for theiruse of urban services such as recreati<strong>on</strong> facilities and libraries, it is neither fair nor efficientto charge them for garbage collecti<strong>on</strong> they do not receive (Vojnovic 1998).87


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?been established to address <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> issues, or satellite offices have beenset up across the <strong>municipal</strong>ity where people can pay tax bills, applyfor building permits, etc. Such devices may – or may not – increaseaccessibility, but they will also to some extent reduce the potentialcost savings that might otherwise result from a larger <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>unit.Also debatable is the extent to which c<strong>on</strong>solidated <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>stake advantage of ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. 7 The empirical evidence is,at best, mixed. 8 Byrnes and Dollery (2002), for example, reviewedresearch <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in the UK and the US and c<strong>on</strong>cludedthat <strong>on</strong>ly 8 percent of the studies found evidence of ec<strong>on</strong>omies ofscale in <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, 29 percent found evidence of U-shapedcost curves, 39 percent found no statistical relati<strong>on</strong>ship between percapita expenditure and populati<strong>on</strong> size, and 24 percent found evidenceof disec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. Studies that analyzed specific services (e.g.fire, housing) also showed mixed results. On the whole, as notedbelow, there appear to be few ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale with respect to mostservices <strong>on</strong>ce <strong>municipal</strong>ities are much larger than 20,000–40,000 orso in populati<strong>on</strong>.Ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale depend <strong>on</strong> the service in questi<strong>on</strong> and the unitsof measurement – such as the jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> size or the size of thefacility. Hirsch (1959), for example, estimated cost functi<strong>on</strong>s forpolice services, fire services, refuse collecti<strong>on</strong>, water, sewage and7 For a good discussi<strong>on</strong> of ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in the provisi<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services, seeFox and Gurley (2006).8 There are also problems with the methodology used to measure cost and output(Byrnes and Dollery 2002). In most studies, expenditures are used as the measure of cost andpopulati<strong>on</strong> is used as the measure of output. Populati<strong>on</strong> may not be the best measure of output.A larger populati<strong>on</strong> may mean greater need for expenditures but the characteristics of thepopulati<strong>on</strong> will also influence need. For example, a <strong>municipal</strong>ity with a large proporti<strong>on</strong> ofelderly will have different expenditure needs than <strong>on</strong>e with a younger populati<strong>on</strong> of the samesize; an urban populati<strong>on</strong> will have different expenditure needs than a rural populati<strong>on</strong>. Thedensity and geographic distributi<strong>on</strong> of populati<strong>on</strong> may also be an important factor affectingboth needs and costs. Furthermore, populati<strong>on</strong> does not reflect the n<strong>on</strong>-resident populati<strong>on</strong>that visits a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> area and uses services. With respect to the measurement ofcost, expenditures are not always the best proxy because they not <strong>on</strong>ly include costs but alsoreflect quality of services and possibly wasteful expenditures. Few studies of ec<strong>on</strong>omies ofscale include service levels.88


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdeducati<strong>on</strong> and found that expenditures per capita declined with thequantity provided for water and sewage (perhaps unsurprisingly,given the very heavy infrastructure comp<strong>on</strong>ent of such services) – butthat there was no similar decline for other urban services generallyprovided by <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in the US. For some services,expenditures per capita actually rose as output expanded, indicatingthat there were disec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. Other studies that haveestimated cost functi<strong>on</strong>s have similarly found ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale forhard services such as water, sewers and transportati<strong>on</strong> but generallynot for such soft services as police, refuse collecti<strong>on</strong>, recreati<strong>on</strong> orplanning (Bird and Slack 1993). Hard services are capital intensive,so large <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> units can more readily make the substantialcapital investments needed to extend the water distributi<strong>on</strong> systemor build a least unit cost size sewage treatment plant, for example(Bahl and Linn 1992). Other services, such as policing, are highlylabour intensive and hence unlikely to show significant ec<strong>on</strong>omies ofscale. Presumably much the same can be said with respect to otherlabour intensive services like social services, educati<strong>on</strong>, and to someextent even health. 9 In terms of the importance of the relative sizeof the <strong>municipal</strong>ities in an amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, Kushner and Siegel (2005)analyzed whether amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s of 29 <strong>municipal</strong>ities in Ontario,Canada (in Central Elgin, Chatham, and Kingst<strong>on</strong>) resulted in moreefficient service delivery. They found lower expenditures followingamalgamati<strong>on</strong> in Central Elgin, a relatively large township whichamalgamated with two small adjacent villages but not in the othertwo amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s which involved <strong>municipal</strong>ities of relatively equalsize.Recent studies in both Canada and Finland have found little evidenceof ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in large <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Found (2012), forexample, analyzed ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale for fire and police in 445<strong>municipal</strong>ities in Ontario, Canada from 2005 to 2008. He foundthat fire services exhibited U-shaped costs with a cost-minimizingpopulati<strong>on</strong> of approximately 20,000 residents. Police services also9 As Baumol (1967) emphasized, it is precisely the high labour-intensity of manypublic sector services that tends to make such services relatively more expensive as incomes(and wages) rise.89


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?exhibited U-shaped costs with a cost-minimizing populati<strong>on</strong> of about45,000 residents. In Finland, Moisio, Loikkanen and Oulasvirta(2010) reported <strong>on</strong> a number of studies of the effects of <strong>municipal</strong>mergers <strong>on</strong> per capita expenditures and found the results to bemixed, with the biggest cities showing relatively low cost efficiencywith respect to basic welfare services. Other studies in Finland thatfocused <strong>on</strong> specific <strong>municipal</strong> services (health centres and schooling)found the optimal size of the <strong>municipal</strong>ity to be somewhere between20,000 and 40,000 people (Moisio, Loikkanen and Oulasvirta, 2010).The ability to achieve ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale depends in part <strong>on</strong> thedensity of development in the new <strong>municipal</strong>ity. A recent study ofannexati<strong>on</strong> analyzed 952 U.S. cities (with at least 10,000 people)that annexed other <strong>municipal</strong>ities between 1992 and 2002 foundefficiencies from increasing land area but <strong>on</strong>ly if the annexati<strong>on</strong>was accompanied by higher densities (Edwards and Xiao 2009). Ifdensities are lower following annexati<strong>on</strong>, per capita expendituresmay increase or decrease depending <strong>on</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship of the changein land area to changes in density. The authors found that servicedelivery and administrative efficiencies are achieved with high densitydevelopments but compromised with low density developments thatare spread out and more costly to serve.On the whole the empirical evidence <strong>on</strong> fragmented versusc<strong>on</strong>solidated <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in the U.S. suggests that c<strong>on</strong>solidatedstructures are generally associated with higher spending (Boyne 1992).Similarly, the promised cost savings from <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>sin Canada have proven to be elusive (Sanct<strong>on</strong> 1996, Slack 2005).When <strong>municipal</strong>ities amalgamate, some duplicati<strong>on</strong> is obviouslyeliminated. 10 In particular, the number of politicians and bureaucratsmay be reduced. On the other hand, when <strong>municipal</strong>ities withdifferent service levels and different wage scales merge, expendituresmay increase. For example, when the fire departments of several<strong>municipal</strong>ities are amalgamated, it is possible to reduce costs by10 Service delivery costs could be reduced without changing <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> boundaries,for example, by providing services from <strong>on</strong>e <strong>municipal</strong>ity to other <strong>municipal</strong>ities or throughwell-designed and m<strong>on</strong>itored c<strong>on</strong>tracting with private sector agents.90


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdeliminating a number of fire chiefs. However, all fire fighters in thenewly amalgamated <strong>municipal</strong>ity are doing the same job and workingfor the same employer – the newly created city. Understandably, theywill want to be paid comparable salaries and benefits, and n<strong>on</strong>e willbe willing to take a pay cut. Salaries and benefits tend to equalize upto the highest expenditure <strong>municipal</strong>ity. This upward harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong>of wages and salaries generally outweighs any cost savings. 11Competiti<strong>on</strong> between <strong>municipal</strong>ities will likely be reduced byamalgamati<strong>on</strong> thus weakening incentives to be efficient, to beresp<strong>on</strong>sive to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> needs and to adapt to changing ec<strong>on</strong>omicc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. Less competiti<strong>on</strong> may also lead to higher tax rates.Charlot, Paty and Piguet (2012), for example, estimated a model oftax setting for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> business tax in French urban <strong>municipal</strong>itiesfrom 1993 to 2003 and c<strong>on</strong>cluded that a reducti<strong>on</strong> in the numberof <strong>municipal</strong>ities limits tax competiti<strong>on</strong> and increases <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> businesstax rates. 12 On the other hand, if some <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>ities could not previouslyafford to provide an adequate level of service at a reas<strong>on</strong>able taxrate because they did not have adequate resources, amalgamati<strong>on</strong>may allow them to provide a level of service comparable to richer<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>ities in the regi<strong>on</strong>.Since mergers seldom result in a political boundary that encompassesthe entire ec<strong>on</strong>omic regi<strong>on</strong> (Bahl 2010) externalities may still existin transportati<strong>on</strong>, land use planning, and other services. Even if thenewly c<strong>on</strong>solidated <strong>municipal</strong>ity is coterminous with the ec<strong>on</strong>omicregi<strong>on</strong> at the time of amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, ec<strong>on</strong>omic boundaries changeover time. Political boundaries, <strong>on</strong> the other hand, are difficult tochange and <strong>on</strong>ly do so occasi<strong>on</strong>ally “in big leaps, and often aftercomplex procedures” (OECD 2006, 157). As a result, many citiesneed to coordinate services such as transportati<strong>on</strong> and planning11 Another reas<strong>on</strong> why costs may increase is that <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s may exploit thelarger tax base of the newly amalgamated <strong>municipal</strong>ity by engaging in last-minute spendingthat results in budget over-runs (Blom-Hansen 2010). Evidence of last-minute spending wasfound in Denmark (Blom-Hansen 2010); evidence of increases in per capita debt prior toamalgamati<strong>on</strong> was found for Sweden (Dahlberg 2010).12 In additi<strong>on</strong>, if inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al transfers to some extent equalize ‘revenuecapacity’, the cartelizati<strong>on</strong> of taxati<strong>on</strong> in the regi<strong>on</strong> is strengthened and, as Smart (1998)shows, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax rates tend to be even higher than they would otherwise be.91


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?with neighbouring <strong>municipal</strong>ities (Slack and Chattopadhyay 2009).Frequently, <strong>on</strong>e way this is d<strong>on</strong>e is through the creati<strong>on</strong> of ‘special’districts to provide such specific services. However, as Berry (2009)shows, any efficiencies achieved through such specializati<strong>on</strong> areoften outweighed by the greater ease with which special interestsmay capture special-purpose (<strong>on</strong>e-issue) governance instituti<strong>on</strong>s.The result is likely to be cost increases to the benefit of interestedparties rather than cost savings or service delivery efficiencies.Horiz<strong>on</strong>tal c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>municipal</strong>ities through amalgamati<strong>on</strong>,merger, or annexati<strong>on</strong> to <strong>on</strong>e tier is not very comm<strong>on</strong> around theworld. In the US and Switzerland the importance attached to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>aut<strong>on</strong>omy means that there is little or no interest in c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong>.In Brazil, larger and richer <strong>municipal</strong>ities fear being exploited bypoorer <strong>municipal</strong>ities. The result is that even when they participatein metropolitan arrangements such fears generally act as an obstacleto their successful operati<strong>on</strong> (Slack and Chattopadhyay 2012).Nevertheless, there have been some noteworthy examples ofamalgamati<strong>on</strong>. In Cape Town, for example, the main rati<strong>on</strong>ale foramalgamati<strong>on</strong> in 2000 was explicitly to redistribute from rich (former‘white’) <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> authorities to poor (former ‘black’) <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> authoritieswithin the metropolitan areas. The boundaries of Cape Town weredeliberately drawn by the Municipal Demarcati<strong>on</strong> Board to mergethe previous black and white authorities. The result is a <strong>on</strong>e-tier<strong>municipal</strong>ity with geographic boundaries that cover the ec<strong>on</strong>omicregi<strong>on</strong>. Louisville, Kentucky, provides an example of a fairly recentcity-county c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> in the US. However, that merger focused<strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> the city and <strong>on</strong>e county <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>; cooperati<strong>on</strong> within thelarger metropolitan regi<strong>on</strong> remains minimal. A more interesting caseis the amalgamati<strong>on</strong> of Tor<strong>on</strong>to in 1998 discussed in Secti<strong>on</strong> 4.92


Enid Slack – Richard M. Bird4.3 Alternatives to <strong>municipal</strong> mergers 13A major problem with amalgamati<strong>on</strong> as a way to address regi<strong>on</strong>alissues in a metropolitan area is the likely loss of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> accessibility to<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> accountability to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents. Thissecti<strong>on</strong> describes briefly three ways in which countries have oftentried to provide a better balance between regi<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s and<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness and accountability – a two-tier model, voluntarycooperati<strong>on</strong>, and special districts.Two-tier modelThe two-tier model c<strong>on</strong>sists of an upper-tier governing body (usuallya regi<strong>on</strong>, district or metropolitan area) encompassing a fairly largegeographic area and lower-tier or area <strong>municipal</strong>ities (such as cities,towns, villages). In principle, the upper tier should be resp<strong>on</strong>siblefor services that provide regi<strong>on</strong>-wide benefits, generate externalities,entail some redistributi<strong>on</strong>, and display ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. Servicesthat provide <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> benefits should be the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility of the lowertier.Redistributi<strong>on</strong> is achieved at the upper-tier level through acombinati<strong>on</strong> of tax and spending policies. Taxes are generally leviedat uniform rates across the regi<strong>on</strong> with the c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of each lowertier<strong>municipal</strong>ity to the upper-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ity depending up<strong>on</strong> thesize of its tax base. The upper-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> makes expenditures<strong>on</strong> services that benefit the entire city-regi<strong>on</strong> and are not necessarilydistributed am<strong>on</strong>g the lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities in the same wayas revenues are collected. A uniform tax at the upper-tier levelcombined with regi<strong>on</strong>-wide expenditures serves to redistributeresources from <strong>municipal</strong>ities with relatively large tax bases tothose with relatively small tax bases. Of course, there may still bedifferentiati<strong>on</strong> in service levels and tax rates with respect to servicesprovided by lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities.13 This secti<strong>on</strong> draws heavily <strong>on</strong> Bird and Slack (2008).93


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?Two-tier governance structures can permit any desired degree ofredistributi<strong>on</strong>. They have potentially important advantages overthe <strong>on</strong>e-tier model in terms of accountability, efficiency, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. Critics of the two-tier model comm<strong>on</strong>ly argue thatcosts will be higher because of waste and duplicati<strong>on</strong> in the provisi<strong>on</strong>of services by two levels of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. However, there is littleevidence to support this argument. Aspects of the provisi<strong>on</strong> of manypublic services can easily be divided am<strong>on</strong>g the tiers. In health andeducati<strong>on</strong>, for example, more specialized (and costly) services canbe provided regi<strong>on</strong>ally with primary services being provided <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>ly.With respect to infrastructure (roads, water, etc.) major capitalprojects can be planned, financed, and managed at the regi<strong>on</strong>al level,with <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>s being dealt with at the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level. Dividingresp<strong>on</strong>sibility in such ways can also make service provisi<strong>on</strong> moreaccountable and resp<strong>on</strong>sive to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> preferences. However, twotierstructures are definitely less transparent and more c<strong>on</strong>fusing totaxpayers who can seldom determine precisely who is resp<strong>on</strong>siblefor what services. Moreover, the existence of two levels of <strong>municipal</strong>council has been said to lead to c<strong>on</strong>siderable “wrangling, inefficientdecisi<strong>on</strong>-making, and delays in implementing policies” (Kitchen2002, 312), although the extent to which this is a problem obviouslydepends to a c<strong>on</strong>siderable extent up<strong>on</strong> the precise governancestructure.Metro Vancouver, Canada is an example of a two-tier systemwhere the regi<strong>on</strong>al district is resp<strong>on</strong>sible for delivering a limitedrange of services to twenty-<strong>on</strong>e <strong>municipal</strong>ities, two unincorporatedareas, and <strong>on</strong>e <strong>municipal</strong>ity (for parks <strong>on</strong>ly). Metro Vancouver isgoverned by three Boards: the Greater Vancouver Regi<strong>on</strong>al DistrictBoard, the Greater Vancouver Sewerage and Drainage Board, andthe Greater Vancouver Water District Board. There is also a MetroVancouver Housing Corporati<strong>on</strong>. 14 Directors are appointed annuallyby their respective <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> councils (<strong>on</strong> the basis of representati<strong>on</strong> bypopulati<strong>on</strong>) from the politicians who are elected to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> councils in14 There is also a separate and independent governing body for Translink, MetroVancouver’s regi<strong>on</strong>al transportati<strong>on</strong> authority.94


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdthe Metro regi<strong>on</strong> and, unsurprisingly, tend more to represent their<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>stituencies than to take a regi<strong>on</strong>al perspective.Barcel<strong>on</strong>a is a more recent example of a two-tier structure. This newbody, which came into being in 2011, replaced three metropolitanbodies: the Metropolitan Entity of Hydraulic Services and WasteManagement (EMSHTR) which covered 33 <strong>municipal</strong>ities,the Metropolitan Transport Entity (EMT) which covered 18<strong>municipal</strong>ities, and the Associati<strong>on</strong> of Municipalities of theMetropolitan Area of Barcel<strong>on</strong>a (MMAMB) which was a voluntarybody made of 31 <strong>municipal</strong>ities Not <strong>on</strong>ly was the metropolitanarea greater than that covered by these metropolitan bodies but theexistence of three different entities in the same metropolitan area,each made up of a different number of <strong>municipal</strong>ities, resulted insubstantial (and unproductive) complexity. Legislati<strong>on</strong> passed by theregi<strong>on</strong>al Parliament in 2010 significantly modified the governanceof Barcel<strong>on</strong>a through the creati<strong>on</strong> of an upper tier metropolitan<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> with 36 lower tier jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s. 15 The MetropolitanCouncil comprises all of the mayors of the <strong>municipal</strong>ities plus 90councillors, the Governing Committee, and the President. ThePresident is elected by the Council from am<strong>on</strong>g the mayors. Thisnew structure may perhaps functi<strong>on</strong> better than that in Vancouverbecause there really is a general metro <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, though it is tooso<strong>on</strong> yet to know.Voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong>Voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> has been described as “minimal” <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>restructuring in which there is an “area-wide body based <strong>on</strong> voluntarycooperati<strong>on</strong> between existing units of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in theagglomerati<strong>on</strong> with no permanent, independent instituti<strong>on</strong>al status”(Sharpe 1995, 12). Such structures, which are comm<strong>on</strong> in the US, arepopular in part because they are easy to create politically and can bedisbanded equally easily. 16 Although the voluntary model does not15 For more informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Barcel<strong>on</strong>a, see Bosch, Espasa, and Solé-Vilanova (2012).16 Although voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> has been comm<strong>on</strong> in France in the past,recent territorial <strong>reform</strong> has resulted in many <strong>municipal</strong>ities joining a two-tier structure(Communautés urbaines) whereby the lower tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities transfer some service95


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?include an elected, area-wide <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, it is an alternative methodof recognizing the inter-relati<strong>on</strong>ship of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>ities within a regi<strong>on</strong>through some form of area-wide arrangement. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the twotiersystem, which seems generally to be imposed from above (by thenati<strong>on</strong>al or provincial level), the voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> model comesfrom below because <strong>municipal</strong>ities choose to cooperate.Cooperati<strong>on</strong> takes different forms in different countries but generallyimplies some degree of administrative integrati<strong>on</strong> as well as somepolitical linkage in that member <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s have some formof representati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the boards. Moreover, as a rule, such cooperativeorganizati<strong>on</strong>s can levy taxes or collect c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s from the<strong>municipal</strong>ities or levy user fees to pay for services.Voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> is thus a way to provide services across aregi<strong>on</strong> without resorting to amalgamati<strong>on</strong>. Municipalities retaintheir aut<strong>on</strong>omy with respect to expenditure and tax decisi<strong>on</strong>s but atthe same time can achieve ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale in service deliveryand address externalities associated with service provisi<strong>on</strong> (Sharpe1995). 17 Bel (2011), for example, found that inter-<strong>municipal</strong>cooperati<strong>on</strong> in 186 <strong>municipal</strong>ities in Spain for solid waste servicesresulted in lower costs in 2000. For <strong>municipal</strong>ities with fewer than20,000 residents, the average cost was 20 percent lower where therewas cooperati<strong>on</strong>. For <strong>municipal</strong>ities with under 10,000 residents, thecosts were 22 percent lower. 18 He attributed these lower costs to theinvolvement of small <strong>municipal</strong>ities and the formati<strong>on</strong> of a separate<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> body (the comarca) to oversee the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> cooperati<strong>on</strong>.resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities and the setting of the tax rate for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> business tax to the upper tier(Gilbert 2011). In 2010, 80 percent of the French populati<strong>on</strong> lived in this type of two-tierstructure.17 In Finland, for example, the smallest <strong>municipal</strong>ities in particular have formedpartnerships and cooperative arrangements with other <strong>municipal</strong>ities and the private sectorto achieve ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale (Moisio 2011b). The most comm<strong>on</strong> form of cooperati<strong>on</strong> is thejoint authority in which membership is voluntary except for hospital services and regi<strong>on</strong>alcouncils where each <strong>municipal</strong>ity is required to bel<strong>on</strong>g by law. Authorities are run by boardsthat are indirectly elected by member <strong>municipal</strong>ities.18 The average cost differences were not significant in cities with a populati<strong>on</strong> over20,000 residents, however, since they already operate at an optimal scale (Bel 2011).96


Enid Slack – Richard M. BirdProblems of accountability may arise when services are provided byanother jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>. The voluntary model can work well when policymakersin the various <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s have the same objectives.It does not work so well, however, when different <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>shave divergent objectives. Some degree of redistributi<strong>on</strong> may ormay not be accepted by the <strong>municipal</strong>ities involved. Cooperati<strong>on</strong>usually involves bargaining, and some <strong>municipal</strong>ities in a regi<strong>on</strong>may not have much with which to bargain. The problems faced bymany metropolitan areas – global competiti<strong>on</strong>, fiscal disparities,sprawl – are so great that any real soluti<strong>on</strong> likely requires a governancestructure that has a permanent instituti<strong>on</strong>al status.The dominant governance model in the metropolitan areas ofZurich and Geneva, as in most of Switzerland, is voluntaryinter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al cooperati<strong>on</strong> (including cooperati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g thethree levels of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> as well as am<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>swithin the metropolitan area). In the case of Geneva, inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>alcooperati<strong>on</strong> extends to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in neighbouring France.Inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al cooperati<strong>on</strong> tends to be purpose-oriented, directedat services such as electricity, waste disposal, and energy supply.Political representati<strong>on</strong> is indirect because decisi<strong>on</strong>-making bodiesfor these cooperative schemes are composed of delegates of themember communes (Kübler and Rochat 2012). Given the high degreeof instituti<strong>on</strong>al fragmentati<strong>on</strong>, this approach to dealing with inter<strong>municipal</strong>externalities is seen in Switzerland as the most pragmaticway of addressing the metropolitan challenges (Kübler and Rochat2012).Brazil also provides some successful instances of inter-<strong>municipal</strong>cooperati<strong>on</strong>. In 2005, the nati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> passed legislati<strong>on</strong> topromote the creati<strong>on</strong> of <strong>municipal</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sortia. The legislati<strong>on</strong> grantslegal status to c<strong>on</strong>sortia which enables them to get loans and offerguarantees <strong>on</strong> their own. Municipal c<strong>on</strong>sortia are also entitled toexercise supervisory, regulatory, and planning roles. When thestate capital is included in an inter-<strong>municipal</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sortium, the state<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> may also (like the federal and cant<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>sin Switzerland) take part. In Belo Horiz<strong>on</strong>te, state level incentives,97


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?in the form of transfers, were behind a successful inter-<strong>municipal</strong>cooperati<strong>on</strong> in health (Arretche 2012).An even less structured form of voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> is throughinter-<strong>municipal</strong> agreements – formal or informal agreements between<strong>municipal</strong>ities to provide specific services, usually with no officialarea-wide body to oversee such arrangements. An example of suchan inter-<strong>municipal</strong> agreement is the c<strong>on</strong>tract services plan in LosAngeles, under which Los Angeles County provides some services<strong>on</strong> behalf of <strong>municipal</strong>ities in the Los Angeles metropolitan area<strong>on</strong> a c<strong>on</strong>tract basis. Similar city-county links occur in other U.S.jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s as well (Sharpe 1995).Such agreements are generally entered into to reduce costs. They canwork well for small services that can be c<strong>on</strong>tracted out or for sharingclearly identifiable costs. Such agreements have proved effective forservices such as fire fighting and emergency dispatch, maintenanceof boundary roads, purchasing in bulk, and issuing debentures. Thisapproach offers no soluti<strong>on</strong>, however, to the need for regi<strong>on</strong>-widecoordinati<strong>on</strong>. Furthermore, inter-<strong>municipal</strong> agreements generallyprovide no clear public accountability except through the c<strong>on</strong>tract oragreement. If something goes wr<strong>on</strong>g, it may be difficult for citizensto know whether to complain to their <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> or to the<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> that has been c<strong>on</strong>tracted to provide the service.Experience suggests that inter-<strong>municipal</strong> agreements may increasethe likelihood of inter-<strong>municipal</strong> litigati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>flicts (GTA TaskForce 1996). Such agreements may be successful in achievingcoordinati<strong>on</strong> and efficiencies for specific services, but they are notsuitable for achieving regi<strong>on</strong>-wide coordinati<strong>on</strong>. Indeed, they havebeen described as sec<strong>on</strong>d-best soluti<strong>on</strong>s to reorganizati<strong>on</strong> that canlead to “an impenetrable jungle of ad hoc commissi<strong>on</strong>s and complexarrangements that even the most c<strong>on</strong>scientious <strong>municipal</strong> voter willnever understand” (Sanct<strong>on</strong> 1993, 33–34).98


Enid Slack – Richard M. BirdSpecial purpose districtsSpecial purpose districts are sometimes used to deliver services thatspill over <strong>municipal</strong> boundaries. Single-purpose special districtsmay provide similar <strong>municipal</strong> services for several <strong>municipal</strong>itiesor manage regi<strong>on</strong>al services with significant externalities. This formof cooperati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>municipal</strong>ities for regi<strong>on</strong>-wide services isused most widely in countries in which there is a history of str<strong>on</strong>gand aut<strong>on</strong>omous <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. In the U.S., for example, <strong>on</strong>ethirdof all <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s are special districts or school districtsAlthough school boards resp<strong>on</strong>sible for educati<strong>on</strong> are often directlyelected, the boards of other special districts are usually indirectlyc<strong>on</strong>trolled by the c<strong>on</strong>stituent <strong>municipal</strong> councils and are resp<strong>on</strong>siblefor the management of such services as transportati<strong>on</strong>, water andwaste management, and ec<strong>on</strong>omic development, well as taxing, pricesetting, and other policy-making.One advantage of special purpose districts is that each service spillovercan be addressed <strong>on</strong> an individual basis. Since it is unlikely that thespillover boundaries are the same for each service, differently sizedspecial districts could be established, such as a regi<strong>on</strong>-wide transitdistrict or a hospital district. 19 Other advantages may include thedelivery of services by professi<strong>on</strong>als with decisi<strong>on</strong>-making somewhatremoved from political influence; the provisi<strong>on</strong> of services usingmore professi<strong>on</strong>al expertise than may be available to the <strong>municipal</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>; and the use of dedicated revenues from user fees tofinance capital expenditures (Bahl and Linn 1992). Moreover, thesalary schedule may be outside of the normal civil service and thushigher salaries can be offered to attract greater talent (Bahl 2010).19 Special districts to some extent illustrate the c<strong>on</strong>cept of functi<strong>on</strong>al, overlapping,competing jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s (FOCJ), which envisages that “welfare could be improvedsubstantially by promoting competiti<strong>on</strong> between newly emerging jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s that areorganized al<strong>on</strong>g functi<strong>on</strong>s instead of territories” (Frey and Eichenberger 1996, 315). Inthis approach, FOCJ are real <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in that they would have enforcement power andwould be able to levy taxes and they would extend over areas defined by the functi<strong>on</strong>sfor which they are resp<strong>on</strong>sible. But they would overlap geographically and individuals andcommunities could choose to which <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al unit they wanted to bel<strong>on</strong>g.99


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?But special purpose bodies also create problems. First, since each bodyhas resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for a single service it is not required to make tradeoffsbetween, for example, expenditures <strong>on</strong> transit and expenditures<strong>on</strong> water and sewers. When there are many independent specialpurpose bodies, it is difficult to coordinate interrelated activities. 20Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, the proliferati<strong>on</strong> of decisi<strong>on</strong>-making bodies has “created adiffuseness of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> organizati<strong>on</strong>s that is difficult for citizensto understand” (Kitchen 1993, 14). Such bodies weaken generalpurpose<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s both through competiti<strong>on</strong> for resourcesand by reducing political accountability (Bird 1995). Thirdly, whennot funded entirely by user charges, there is no direct link betweenthe expenditure decisi<strong>on</strong>s made by the special purpose agencies andthe <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> councils resp<strong>on</strong>sible for collecting taxes to fund them. Theabsence of what Bret<strong>on</strong> (1996) calls the ‘Wicksellian c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>’between expenditures and revenues reduces accountability. 21 Becauseaccountability is lacking, there is no incentive to be efficient: a higherlevel of technical efficiency through more professi<strong>on</strong>al managementis not the same thing as ec<strong>on</strong>omic efficiency. Services may be betterdelivered but they are not necessarily delivered to the right people inthe right quantities and qualities (Bird 1980). Moreover, such ‘specialpurpose’ jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s are more likely to be captured by specialinterest groups – including public employees – whose decisi<strong>on</strong>s tendto increase costs and alter service provisi<strong>on</strong> in ways not necessarilydesired by those whose interests the jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> is supposed toserve. Berry (2009) finds that “c<strong>on</strong>current taxati<strong>on</strong>” with territoriallyoverlapping <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> special-purpose fiscal jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s taxing the same20 Three ways have been suggested to address coordinati<strong>on</strong> problems (Bahl and Linn1992). One is to have overlapping membership so that some of the same people are <strong>on</strong> anumber of district boards. This may help coordinati<strong>on</strong> but does nothing about accountability.Another is to encourage districts with multi-functi<strong>on</strong>s instead of single-purpose districts: atthe limit of course, this leads back to general-purpose <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Finally, even if specialdistricts remain separate authorities they may be made subject to political c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s inthe decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process (as with elected U.S. school boards).21 As noted by Locke and Tass<strong>on</strong>yi (1993), in Ontario, Canada, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>municipal</strong>ities,which are resp<strong>on</strong>sible for collecting all property taxes, must take into account taxes leviedby the upper tier and (at the time of their study) by school boards when they set their ownlevy but they have no c<strong>on</strong>trol over school board levies and <strong>on</strong>ly limited influence <strong>on</strong> theupper tier.100


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdbase almost invariably raises both tax and spending levels with n<strong>on</strong>oticeable increase in service levels or quality. 22Final observati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> governance structureNeither theory nor practice tells us clearly which model of governanceis best for large metropolitan areas. 23 N<strong>on</strong>etheless, it is clear thata str<strong>on</strong>g regi<strong>on</strong>al structure encompassing the entire city-regi<strong>on</strong>is important. Metropolitan areas are characterized both by str<strong>on</strong>ginter-dependencies (social, ec<strong>on</strong>omic, envir<strong>on</strong>mental, and politicaladministrative)and by externalities am<strong>on</strong>g <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s (Klink2008). Some form of regi<strong>on</strong>al structure is needed to address suchregi<strong>on</strong>al problems as fiscal disparities am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>municipal</strong>ities andexternalities in service provisi<strong>on</strong>. A regi<strong>on</strong>al structure is also neededto resolve transportati<strong>on</strong> and envir<strong>on</strong>mental coordinati<strong>on</strong> issues andto ensure the ec<strong>on</strong>omic competitiveness, social cohesi<strong>on</strong>, and fiscalviability of city-regi<strong>on</strong>s in the global ec<strong>on</strong>omic setting. Few problemsand processes stop at <strong>municipal</strong> boundaries, and many soluti<strong>on</strong>srequire access to a larger pool of resources, both human and financial,than is likely to be at the disposal of small <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. Someform of regi<strong>on</strong>al structure seems necessary if cities are to takefull advantage of new and emerging opportunities for ec<strong>on</strong>omiccooperati<strong>on</strong> and for enhancing productivity and competitiveness inan increasingly knowledge-based ec<strong>on</strong>omy.But what kind of regi<strong>on</strong>al structure is needed? Lefèvre (2008)emphasizes the key characteristics of an effective regi<strong>on</strong>al structureas political legitimacy through direct electi<strong>on</strong>, geographic boundariesthat match the functi<strong>on</strong>al territory of the metropolitan regi<strong>on</strong>,independent financial resources, relevant powers and resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities,and adequate staffing. Yet, voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> and special purpose22 “Special-district libraries spent more but provided fewer books. Their employeeswere less likely to be actual librarians. Despite spending more, district libraries did notattract more patr<strong>on</strong>s, and therefore their efficiency was significantly lower than that of<strong>municipal</strong>ly operated libraries. In other words, district libraries spent more per patr<strong>on</strong> visitand more per circulati<strong>on</strong> transacti<strong>on</strong>” (Berry 2009, 183).23 Other reviews of this issue have also c<strong>on</strong>cluded that no model fits all cases orstands out clearly above the rest (Klink 2008; Divay and Wolfe 2002; Stren and Camer<strong>on</strong>2005).101


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?districts which have few of these characteristics are popular aroundthe world while amalgamati<strong>on</strong> is unpopular. As Daffl<strong>on</strong> (2012, 7)notes, amalgamati<strong>on</strong> is usually justified for ec<strong>on</strong>omic reas<strong>on</strong>s –administrative ec<strong>on</strong>omies, ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale, improved efficiency,internalizati<strong>on</strong> of spillovers, and more robust tax bases – butopp<strong>on</strong>ents justify their positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the basis of democratic arguments– voice and free democratic choice at the grass roots level.Voluntary cooperati<strong>on</strong> may be effective in providing some servicesbut it tilts the balance towards <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> aut<strong>on</strong>omy and resp<strong>on</strong>sivenessand away from ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale, service coordinati<strong>on</strong>, and aregi<strong>on</strong>al visi<strong>on</strong>. This approach is unlikely to provide an adequateregi<strong>on</strong>al foundati<strong>on</strong> for metropolitan areas. Where special districtsare created to deliver specific services not <strong>on</strong>ly is the regi<strong>on</strong>al visi<strong>on</strong>further diluted but in additi<strong>on</strong>, since the boards of special districtsare generally appointed or indirectly elected from members of the<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> councils, accountability to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> citizens is compromised. Ashift from inter-<strong>municipal</strong> cooperative governance structures to aregi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> structure with direct electi<strong>on</strong> would improvepolitical legitimacy but almost inevitably at the expense of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. At the very least, there would need to be some formof community or neighbourhood councils to balance regi<strong>on</strong>al and<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> interests.The real choice for effective governance in a metropolitan regi<strong>on</strong>comes down to <strong>on</strong>e-tier vs. two-tier. Because a <strong>on</strong>e-tier (horiz<strong>on</strong>tal)structure is simpler to understand and more transparent than a twotierstructure it may enhance political and fiscal accountability. Twotier(vertical) structures are inherently more complex and may resultin undesirable duplicati<strong>on</strong>, overlap, and general c<strong>on</strong>fusi<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>gcitizens as to who is resp<strong>on</strong>sible for what and who is paying for it.On the other hand, a two-tier structure may achieve greater efficiencythan is likely to be attained in a more centralized <strong>on</strong>e-tier structure.Desirable ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale and scope can be realized at the uppertier level while at the same time the c<strong>on</strong>tinued existence and vitalityof the lower tier permits more resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> variati<strong>on</strong>s inpreferences and maintains the linkage between <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> financing and102


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdspending decisi<strong>on</strong>. Any desired degree of regi<strong>on</strong>al redistributi<strong>on</strong>can be achieved within either a <strong>on</strong>e-tier or a two-tier structure, althoughobviously most easily – perhaps because less politically transparently– in a <strong>on</strong>e-tier structure with uniform tax rates across the city-regi<strong>on</strong>in which all taxes are made available for redistributi<strong>on</strong>. This seems tohave been the principal reas<strong>on</strong> for the choice of the <strong>on</strong>e-tier model inSouth Africa (Steytler 2012).4.4 The case of Tor<strong>on</strong>to: Back to the future?Tor<strong>on</strong>to was a single tier city until 1954 when a two-tier metropolitan<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sisting of a metropolitan tier, the then City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to,and six lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities was created. Since 1998, it has beena single tier (c<strong>on</strong>solidated) city. The creati<strong>on</strong> of the two-tier structurein 1954 was applauded around the world for its ability to addressgrowth issues and build needed infrastructure <strong>on</strong> a regi<strong>on</strong>-wide basiswhile meeting <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> needs. The most recent amalgamati<strong>on</strong> in 1998which saw the merger of the metropolitan and lower tiers to create asingle-tier City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to was less well received because people feltthat it did not address the regi<strong>on</strong>al issues facing Tor<strong>on</strong>to and that itwas less <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>ly resp<strong>on</strong>sive than the system it replaced.Two-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>Prior to 1953, the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to was surrounded by twelve<strong>municipal</strong>ities that had been growing rapidly in the post-war period. 24Since the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to had no vacant land for the single-familyhousing developments that accommodated most of the growingregi<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>, most growth took place in the suburban<strong>municipal</strong>ities. This growth placed huge demands <strong>on</strong> the capacityof these relatively small <strong>municipal</strong>ities to provide services and suchinfrastructure as educati<strong>on</strong>al facilities, roads, sidewalks, lighting,24 The twelve <strong>municipal</strong>ities included the Town of Leaside, Town of Mimico, Townof New Tor<strong>on</strong>to, Town of West<strong>on</strong>, Village of Forest Hill, Village of L<strong>on</strong>g Branch, Villageof Swansea, Township of East York, Township of Etobicoke, Township of North York,Township of Scarborough, and Township of York.103


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?sewage disposal, and so <strong>on</strong>. An additi<strong>on</strong>al problem was that sincethese <strong>municipal</strong>ities were largely residential, they did not have anadequate tax base to finance the needed infrastructure. The City ofTor<strong>on</strong>to, <strong>on</strong> the other hand, which had significant commercial andindustrial property, also had a solid financial base as a result. 25In additi<strong>on</strong> to the service demands and inadequate resources in thesuburbs, the political boundaries of the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to no l<strong>on</strong>gerreflected the social and ec<strong>on</strong>omic realities of the metropolitanarea (Kulisek and Price 1988). Not withstanding cooperati<strong>on</strong> withsurrounding <strong>municipal</strong>ities, planning was restricted to the boundariesof the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to. Further problems arose because each<strong>municipal</strong>ity acted independently with respect to transportati<strong>on</strong>, landuse, and housing – issues that needed to be addressed <strong>on</strong> a regi<strong>on</strong>widebasis.In resp<strong>on</strong>se to these problems, in 1954 Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>to wascreated by provincial legislati<strong>on</strong>. 26 The Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>to Actestablished a two-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> with a metropolitan tier andthirteen lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities (the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to plus the twelvesuburban <strong>municipal</strong>ities). The metropolitan <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> (Metro) wasinitially given resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for planning, borrowing, assessment,transportati<strong>on</strong> (transit and some roads), and the administrati<strong>on</strong>of justice. Local area <strong>municipal</strong>ities were resp<strong>on</strong>sible for fireprotecti<strong>on</strong>, garbage collecti<strong>on</strong> and disposal, licensing and inspecti<strong>on</strong>,<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> distributi<strong>on</strong> of hydro-electric power, policing, public health,general welfare assistance, 27 recreati<strong>on</strong> and community services, andthe collecti<strong>on</strong> of taxes. Both tiers shared resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for parks,planning, roads and traffic c<strong>on</strong>trol, sewage disposal, and watersupply. Costs were shared <strong>on</strong> the basis of property tax base. This25 The <strong>on</strong>ly tax base open to <strong>municipal</strong>ities in Ontario was real property and residentialproperties have l<strong>on</strong>g been taxed much less heavily than n<strong>on</strong>-residential (commercial andindustrial) properties: for a detailed examinati<strong>on</strong> of the development and operati<strong>on</strong> of theOntario property tax system, see Bird, Slack and Tass<strong>on</strong>yi (2012).26 In Canada, all aspects of <strong>municipal</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> – their boundaries, theirresp<strong>on</strong>sibilities, their taxing powers – are completely c<strong>on</strong>trolled by the provincial<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s.27 The costs of general welfare assistance are shared with the provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.104


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdmeant that, in 1954, the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to picked up 62 percent of thecosts of Metro. 28Over time, many lower tier resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities migrated up to the Metrolevel. Metro took over resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for police services, socialassistance, traffic c<strong>on</strong>trol and operati<strong>on</strong>s, licensing, c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong>,waste disposal, and ambulance services. In 1967, following therecommendati<strong>on</strong>s of a provincially-commissi<strong>on</strong>ed report, thenumber of <strong>municipal</strong>ities in Metro was reduced from thirteen tosix. 29 Property assessment and the administrati<strong>on</strong> of justice becameprovincial resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities in 1970.Early reviews of Metro <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> applauded its success in meetingits intended objectives: “the creati<strong>on</strong> of a federated form of metropolitan<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> for the city of Tor<strong>on</strong>to and its 12 suburbs in 1953 and therapidity with which it was able to overcome serious public servicedeficiencies made the Tor<strong>on</strong>to model an object of admirati<strong>on</strong> forstudents of metropolitan affairs throughout the c<strong>on</strong>tinent” (Frisken1993). The new governance structure provided the necessaryinfrastructure for the orderly growth of the suburbs, maintained avibrant core, and pooled revenues over the whole metropolitan area.It solved the water and sewage treatment problems, c<strong>on</strong>structed rapidtransit lines, established a network of arterial highways, built housingfor seniors, and created a Metro parks system.Spillovers of benefits from transportati<strong>on</strong> and planning were nowc<strong>on</strong>tained within Metro’s borders. Redistributi<strong>on</strong> from the Cityof Tor<strong>on</strong>to to the suburbs enabled the latter to provide neededinfrastructure. Local aut<strong>on</strong>omy was achieved by maintainingthe ability to differentiate <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services across the lower tiers:for example, waste collecti<strong>on</strong> in the former Village of Forest Hill28 See the Report of the Royal Commissi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>to as cited inSanct<strong>on</strong> (1994).29 Forest Hill and Swansea were amalgamated with Tor<strong>on</strong>to, New Tor<strong>on</strong>to, Mimico,and L<strong>on</strong>g Branch with Etobicoke, West<strong>on</strong> with York, and Leaside with East York, whileNorth York and Scarborough (with Etobicoke, York, and East York) became the fiveboroughs which, together with the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to, c<strong>on</strong>stituted the Metro regi<strong>on</strong>.105


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?c<strong>on</strong>tinued to be twice weekly instead of <strong>on</strong>ce a week, as in the restof Metro.The challenges facing Metro began to change in the 1970s, however,as expansi<strong>on</strong> in the regi<strong>on</strong> migrated outside the boundaries ofMetropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>to. No l<strong>on</strong>ger was the problem to accommodategrowth within Metro; instead, growth increasingly occurred in whatbecame known as the Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to Area (GTA). Recognizing thisreality, the province’s first reacti<strong>on</strong> was in the early 1970s to createfour new two-tier regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s around Metro – Durham,Halt<strong>on</strong>, Peel and York. It was not until 1988, however, that theprovince established the Office of the Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to Area (OGTA)to encourage Metro and the surrounding regi<strong>on</strong>s to coordinate theirefforts with respect to a number of critical areas – waste disposal,regi<strong>on</strong>al transportati<strong>on</strong>, land use, and infrastructure planning. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, a forum of GTA mayors (of the lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities)and chairs (of the regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s) was established to encourageand market ec<strong>on</strong>omic development in the GTA.In resp<strong>on</strong>se to growing c<strong>on</strong>cerns about the future ec<strong>on</strong>omicperformance of the urban regi<strong>on</strong> as whole, a GTA Task Force wasestablished in 1995. The Task Force report emphasized the need totreat the entire GTA as a single ec<strong>on</strong>omic unit with a unified ec<strong>on</strong>omicstrategy and to create a new GTA <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al body both to dealmore effectively with GTA-wide envir<strong>on</strong>mental and planning issuesand to share major infrastructure and social costs (GTA Task Force1996). The report also recommended that <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> withinthe GTA should be simplified by creating a Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to Councilfor the regi<strong>on</strong>, eliminating Tor<strong>on</strong>to’s upper tier (Metro) as well as theother four GTA regi<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, and reducing the number oflower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities through further amalgamati<strong>on</strong>.Yet another expert group was appointed by the provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>,the Who Does What (WDW) Panel, in 1996. This group too called<strong>on</strong> the Province to set up a governance structure for the GTA asa whole. Specifically, it recommended the creati<strong>on</strong> of a GreaterTor<strong>on</strong>to Services Board (GTSB), the eliminati<strong>on</strong> of the five upper-106


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdtier (metropolitan and regi<strong>on</strong>al) <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, and the c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong>of some of the lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities into str<strong>on</strong>g cities. However,there was no c<strong>on</strong>sensus within the Panel <strong>on</strong> whether the six lowertier<strong>municipal</strong>ities in Metro Tor<strong>on</strong>to should be merged into <strong>on</strong>e cityor four cities.One-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>Despite these repeated recommendati<strong>on</strong>s by provinciallycommissi<strong>on</strong>edreports <strong>on</strong> the need to coordinate service deliverybetween Tor<strong>on</strong>to and the surrounding regi<strong>on</strong>s, the provincial<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> chose instead simply to amalgamate the <strong>municipal</strong>itieswithin Tor<strong>on</strong>to. The stated rati<strong>on</strong>ale was to save taxpayers’ m<strong>on</strong>eyby replacing six lower-tier <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s and the metropolitan levelof <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> with <strong>on</strong>e <strong>municipal</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> – the new City ofTor<strong>on</strong>to. Since in Canadian <strong>municipal</strong> affairs provinces get whatprovinces want the result was that a new unified City of Tor<strong>on</strong>towas created by the province <strong>on</strong> January 1, 1998. The upper-tier(metropolitan) <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> and six <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> area <strong>municipal</strong>ities weremerged into a single-tier city.This restructuring did not arise from <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiative. Indeed, oppositi<strong>on</strong>to the proposed amalgamati<strong>on</strong> came from many different quarters:<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>municipal</strong>ities (both inside and outside of Metro Tor<strong>on</strong>to), theoppositi<strong>on</strong> parties in the provincial legislature, citizen organizati<strong>on</strong>s,and even from within the governing party itself (Stevens<strong>on</strong> and Gilbert1999). Prior to the passage of the legislati<strong>on</strong>, referenda were heldin each of the lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities in Metro Tor<strong>on</strong>to. Although<strong>on</strong>ly 36 percent of eligible voters voted, oppositi<strong>on</strong> to the proposedamalgamated City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to ranged from 70 to 81 percent of voters,depending <strong>on</strong> the <strong>municipal</strong>ity. The major citizen oppositi<strong>on</strong> centred<strong>on</strong> the loss of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> identity and reduced access to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.In the broader c<strong>on</strong>text of the GTA, <strong>municipal</strong>ities outside of Tor<strong>on</strong>towere c<strong>on</strong>cerned that Metro amalgamati<strong>on</strong> would result in increasedpolarizati<strong>on</strong> within the regi<strong>on</strong>.Once Tor<strong>on</strong>to was amalgamated the provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> so<strong>on</strong>established the Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to Services Board (GTSB) initially107


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?suggested by the Who Does What Panel in 1996. 30 However, theGTSB was given no legislative authority except to oversee regi<strong>on</strong>altransit with some limited powers to coordinate decisi<strong>on</strong>-makingam<strong>on</strong>g its member <strong>municipal</strong>ities and to provide strategic growthmanagement. It was not designed to be a level of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> norwas it given direct taxing authority. The GTSB comprised electedrepresentatives from each of the <strong>municipal</strong>ities in the regi<strong>on</strong>. Areview of the GTSB in 2001 c<strong>on</strong>cluded that to have any real effectthe role and powers of the Board should be strengthened significantlythrough provincial legislati<strong>on</strong> to include resp<strong>on</strong>sibility to develop agrowth management strategy and to create a transportati<strong>on</strong> authorityfor the regi<strong>on</strong> that would address growing transportati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns(Deloitte C<strong>on</strong>sulting 2001). Later that year, however, the provincial<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> disbanded the GTSB. There c<strong>on</strong>tinues to be no effectiveregi<strong>on</strong>al governance structure in the Tor<strong>on</strong>to metropolitan regi<strong>on</strong>. 31Within Tor<strong>on</strong>to, however, the governance structure was substantiallysimplified. The City Council comprises a Mayor who is elected atlarge and 44 councillors elected in wards (c<strong>on</strong>stituencies). Decisi<strong>on</strong>sare made by the Council, however, and not the Mayor: this isdefinitely not a ‘str<strong>on</strong>g mayor’ system because the mayor has <strong>on</strong>ly<strong>on</strong>e vote <strong>on</strong> council. 32 In additi<strong>on</strong> to the str<strong>on</strong>g community affiliati<strong>on</strong>of most of City Councillors, there are community councils intendedboth to deal with <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> issues that pertain to the community andneighbourhood (such as traffic plans, parking regulati<strong>on</strong>s, signs, andfence, ravine and tree by-laws) as well as to provide a place for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>30 The Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to Services Board Act, 1998 sets out the structure andresp<strong>on</strong>sibilities of the Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to Services Board (GTSB).31 There has been some sharing of costs, however. Following the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>,the provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> introduced pooling of the <strong>municipal</strong> porti<strong>on</strong> of social service costsin the GTA. Because social service costs are much higher in the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to than therest of the regi<strong>on</strong>, pooling meant that the regi<strong>on</strong>s were paying taxes for services in Tor<strong>on</strong>towithout any say over how their tax dollars were being spent. The obvious resentment <strong>on</strong> thepart of the regi<strong>on</strong>s led to pooling (which they referred to as the “Tor<strong>on</strong>to tax”) eventuallybeing phased out.32 Under the new City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to Act passed in 2006, the mayor was given someadditi<strong>on</strong>al powers such as the ability to set the council agenda for the coming term and toappoint members of a new Executive Committee that focuses <strong>on</strong> priority setting for council.The mayor has not been the given power to appoint and direct city officials or to veto councildecisi<strong>on</strong>s as in the US-style “str<strong>on</strong>g mayor” system, however.108


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdinput into council’s decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process. Community councilsare composed of elected officials representing between 10 and 12electoral wards. Each member of council serves <strong>on</strong> the communitycouncil that incorporates his/her ward.Although amalgamati<strong>on</strong> was not popular when it came into forceover a decade ago, there is little interest in dismantling it today. And,although many have c<strong>on</strong>tinued to express the need for a regi<strong>on</strong>alauthority for the GTA and bey<strong>on</strong>d, there c<strong>on</strong>tinues to be little politicalinterest in creating such a body at either the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> or provincial levels.Provincial politicians may perhaps see creating a regi<strong>on</strong>al authoritythat would c<strong>on</strong>tain about half the provincial populati<strong>on</strong> and a muchhigher share of ec<strong>on</strong>omic activity as c<strong>on</strong>stituting too direct a challengeto their interests and power base. Similarly, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> politicians outsideTor<strong>on</strong>to may fear that City politicians would play too dominant a rolein any regi<strong>on</strong>al entity.What ‘regi<strong>on</strong>al governance’ there is lies largely in the hands of theprovince. For example, the provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> has in effect largelytaken over resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for transportati<strong>on</strong> and land use planningfor the Tor<strong>on</strong>to regi<strong>on</strong>. Metrolinx (originally the Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>toTransit Authority) was created by the province to be resp<strong>on</strong>siblefor transportati<strong>on</strong> in the regi<strong>on</strong>. Provincial legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> growthmanagement (Places to Grow Act, 2005 and the Greenbelt Act, 2005)has put the province squarely in charge of regi<strong>on</strong>al land use planning.The Places to Grow Act gives the province the authority to designateany geographic regi<strong>on</strong> of the province as a growth plan area; developa growth plan in c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong> with <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> officials, stakeholders,public groups, and members of the public; and develop growthplans in any part of Ontario. The greenbelt legislati<strong>on</strong> authorizes theprovincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> to designate a Greenbelt Area and establish aGreenbelt Plan for the Tor<strong>on</strong>to regi<strong>on</strong> (defined more broadly than theGTA). Moreover, as has l<strong>on</strong>g been true, the development of majorwater and sewer facilities – essentially in effect a provincialresp<strong>on</strong>sibility – c<strong>on</strong>tinues to be a major factor shaping wheredevelopment actually takes place.109


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?What has amalgamati<strong>on</strong> achieved?Amalgamati<strong>on</strong> in Tor<strong>on</strong>to has resulted in the creati<strong>on</strong> of a city that is,at the same time, too small and too big. The city is too small to addressthe regi<strong>on</strong>al issues that plague the GTA (such as transportati<strong>on</strong> andland use planning and ec<strong>on</strong>omic development) and yet it is too big tobe very resp<strong>on</strong>sive to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents. Moreover, it is highly unlikelythat amalgamati<strong>on</strong> has resulted in any significant cost savings.Amalgamati<strong>on</strong> had not visibly been <strong>on</strong> any<strong>on</strong>e’s agenda beforeit became reality. Most efforts of the provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> hadbeen directed at addressing regi<strong>on</strong>al issues across the entire GreaterTor<strong>on</strong>to Area. The OGTA, for example, focussed <strong>on</strong> a strategic visi<strong>on</strong>for the GTA and the coordinati<strong>on</strong> of regi<strong>on</strong>al issues; the forum ofGTA mayors and chairs c<strong>on</strong>centrated <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic development andmarketing in the GTA; and the GTA Task Force and the Who DoesWhat Panel both emphasized the need for a <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> body to coverthe entire regi<strong>on</strong>. The major policy c<strong>on</strong>cern was the coordinati<strong>on</strong> ofservice delivery across the regi<strong>on</strong> and, in particular, the coordinati<strong>on</strong>of transportati<strong>on</strong> and land use planning, water provisi<strong>on</strong>, and wastemanagement. Neither the creati<strong>on</strong> of the new City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to nor theGTSB adequately addressed these fundamental regi<strong>on</strong>al problems.The boundaries of the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to made it too small to addressthe regi<strong>on</strong>al issues; the GTSB was not given sufficient authority toaccomplish anything and was so<strong>on</strong> dissolved. Regi<strong>on</strong>al land useplanning and transportati<strong>on</strong> issues remain essentially in the hands ofthe provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Cost savings?One of the main issues around Tor<strong>on</strong>to’s amalgamati<strong>on</strong> was theability to save costs. 33 At its simplest the argument that reducing thenumber of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s will cut costs is true in the sense thatamalgamati<strong>on</strong> in all likelihood will reduce the number of politiciansand administrators. However, it is equally true that the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>of <strong>municipal</strong>ities with different service levels and different wage33 This secti<strong>on</strong> draws heavily from Slack (2000).110


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdscales tends to result in expenditure increases. As Tindal (1996, 50)notes: “past experience tells us that there are str<strong>on</strong>g upward pressures<strong>on</strong> costs after an amalgamati<strong>on</strong>.”In the case of Tor<strong>on</strong>to, potential cost savings were fairly small since thethree largest expenditures (welfare assistance, transit, and policing)were already Metro resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities before the 1998 amalgamati<strong>on</strong>. 34These three services accounted for 70 percent of the total upper-tierand lower-tier expenditures combined. Potential cost savings werethus limited to 30 percent of the total budget of the new city.Some savings did occur, mostly from staff reducti<strong>on</strong>s. Between 1998and 2002, 2,700 positi<strong>on</strong>s were eliminated through amalgamati<strong>on</strong>.Over the same time period, however, an additi<strong>on</strong>al 3,600 positi<strong>on</strong>swere added to improve service levels, with the overall result beinga net increase in employment over the period (Schwartz 2004).Unfortunately, it is not possible to determine the extent to which thesenew positi<strong>on</strong>s may have been created in resp<strong>on</strong>se to the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>since a wide variety of other provincial initiatives affecting <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending were also introduced in 1998. 35In an attempt to determine the l<strong>on</strong>g-term effect of amalgamati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending, we assembled for four services – fire, garbage,libraries, and parks and recreati<strong>on</strong> – a data base of expenditures perhousehold in c<strong>on</strong>stant 2008$ for the six lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities(and, for some services, also for Metro) from 1988 to 1997 and for theamalgamated city from 1998 to 2008. 36 Fire and garbage expenditureswere chosen because they were solely lower-tier expenditures beforethe amalgamati<strong>on</strong>. Although parks and recreati<strong>on</strong> as well as librarieswere also largely lower-tier resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities, each had a small upper-34 The provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> based much of its case <strong>on</strong> the potential savings from theTor<strong>on</strong>to amalgamati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> a study it had commissi<strong>on</strong>ed (KPMG 1996). This study, however,estimated cost savings in the area of policing, a service that had already been amalgamatedin 1967. The study also did not estimate the potential impact of the harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> of wagesand salaries and services that would occur following the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>.35 In particular, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services realignment described briefly below (and in moredetail in Bird, Slack and Tass<strong>on</strong>yi 2012).36 We are most grateful to Adam Found for invaluable assistance in assembling andanalysing these data.111


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?tier comp<strong>on</strong>ent. Of the 30 percent of total expenditures where therewas potential for cost savings (i.e. those that were not alreadyamalgamated at the upper tier), these four services accounted forabout 40 percent of lower tier expenditures prior to amalgamati<strong>on</strong>. 37Another reas<strong>on</strong> for focusing <strong>on</strong> these four services is because theywere not affected by the province-wide <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services realignmentthat also occurred in 1998. This realignment resulted in the transferof full resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for many previously cost-shared servicessuch as water, sewers, roads, transit, social housing, public health,ambulances, and some increased resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for social servicesto <strong>municipal</strong>ities. In return, the provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> uploadedprimary and sec<strong>on</strong>dary educati<strong>on</strong> from school boards and a few otherservices from <strong>municipal</strong>ities to the provincial level. 38 Unfortunately,it is not possible to separate the impact of amalgamati<strong>on</strong> from theimpact of the services realignment for the downloaded activities.37 This estimate does not include the porti<strong>on</strong> of libraries and parks that were alreadyat the upper tier.38 At the same time, the provincial <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> took over tax rate setting for theeducati<strong>on</strong> porti<strong>on</strong> of the property tax and lowered the residential tax rate to give tax room to<strong>municipal</strong>ities.112


Enid Slack – Richard M. BirdFigure 1 Fire expenditures per household 1988–2008Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>toScarboroughTor<strong>on</strong>toEast YorkNorth YorkYorkEtobicokeMetro TotalAmalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>toLin. (Metro Total)Lin. (Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>to)$500$450$400$350$300$250$200$150$100$50$0198719881989199019911992199319941995199<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>997199819992000200120022003200420052006200720082009For fire services, expenditures per household before amalgamati<strong>on</strong>were much higher in the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to than in the other<strong>municipal</strong>ities. This difference likely reflects the higher density of thedowntown area and the c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> of commercial buildings. Thelinear trend line for all fire expenditures even in Tor<strong>on</strong>to, howeveris, as Figure 1 shows, downward sloping prior to amalgamati<strong>on</strong>; 39after amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, the trend is upward sloping. Fire expenditureshave clearly increased since amalgamati<strong>on</strong>. Of course, in some caseshigher expenditures may mean higher service levels; in other cases,they may reflect the increased need for specialized services as newcommercial growth took place outside the central business district(i.e. the former city of Tor<strong>on</strong>to). Unfortunately, no c<strong>on</strong>sistent andcomparable informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> changes in either costs (e.g. wages) orservice levels (e.g. resp<strong>on</strong>se times) is available.39 The dotted line in each graph shows the linear predicted trend for the newlyamalgamated city from 1998 to 2008. The solid line shows the trend for the Metro total(upper and lower tiers) from 1988 to 1997 and hence where the pre-amalgamati<strong>on</strong> structurewould have ended up had the 1988 to 1997 trend persisted.113


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?Figure 2Garbage collecti<strong>on</strong> expenditures per household,1988–2008$250Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>toTor<strong>on</strong>toNorth YorkEtobicokeAmalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>toLin. (Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>to)ScarboroughEast YorkYorkMetro TotalLin. (Metro Total)$200$150$100$50$0198719881989199019911992199319941995199<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>997199819992000200120022003200420052006200720082009As Figure 2 shows, the trends with respect to expenditures <strong>on</strong> garbagecollecti<strong>on</strong> are similar. As with fire services, these costs were higherin the former City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to than other lower-tier <strong>municipal</strong>itiesprior to amalgamati<strong>on</strong>. This difference likely reflects the factthat the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to provided pickup service to commercialproperties whereas other <strong>municipal</strong>ities did not as well as the greaterproporti<strong>on</strong> of such properties in the City. Again, however, the trend inexpenditures <strong>on</strong> garbage collecti<strong>on</strong> was downward both in total and inthe former City prior to amalgamati<strong>on</strong> but turned upward followingthe amalgamati<strong>on</strong>. As with fire services, it is not clear to what extentthe expenditure increase reflects higher wages and salaries or higherservice levels. Interestingly, <strong>on</strong>e <strong>municipal</strong>ity (Etobicoke) c<strong>on</strong>tractedout garbage collecti<strong>on</strong> to the private sector before amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, andprivate sector delivery remained for that part of the new city afteramalgamati<strong>on</strong>.114


Enid Slack – Richard M. BirdFigure 3Parks and recreati<strong>on</strong> axpenditures per household,1988–2008$600Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>toTor<strong>on</strong>toNorth YorkEtobicokeAmalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>toLin. (Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>to)ScarboroughEast YorkYorkMetro TotalLin. (Metro Total)$500$400$300$200$100$0198719881989199019911992199319941995199<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>997199819992000200120022003200420052006200720082009The effect of amalgamati<strong>on</strong> appears again to increase the expendituretrend for parks and recreati<strong>on</strong> (Figure 3). For libraries, however, theprevious downward trend in expenditures per household c<strong>on</strong>tinuedafter amalgamati<strong>on</strong> (Figure 4) even though service levels almostcertainly increased since access to the library system for the wholemetropolitan area was much easier following the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>.This decline is especially noteworthy in a period in which the natureof public library service changed markedly from handing out booksto providing electr<strong>on</strong>ic and internet services.115


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?Figure 4 Libraries expenditures per household, 1988–2008Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>to Scarborough Tor<strong>on</strong>toEast York North York YorkEtobicoke Metro Total Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>toLin. (Metro Total)Lin. (Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>to)$300$250$200$150$100$50$0198719881989199019911992199319941995199<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>997199819992000200120022003200420052006200720082009To the extent higher costs are associated with the equalizati<strong>on</strong> ofservice levels they are not necessarily bad. If some <strong>municipal</strong>itiesprovide lower levels of services than their citizens would havepreferred simply because they do not have adequate resources,amalgamati<strong>on</strong> allows them to provide at least the same level ofservice as other <strong>municipal</strong>ities in the regi<strong>on</strong>. But this means thatcosts are likely to rise, not fall. For example, the former City of Yorkand the former Borough of East York were experiencing decliningtax bases (assessments) and hence inadequate levels of service.Amalgamati<strong>on</strong> likely increased the level of services for residentsin these two <strong>municipal</strong>ities and hence resulted in increased equitywithin the former metropolitan area.In additi<strong>on</strong> to the harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> of service levels and wages andsalaries, <strong>municipal</strong> amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s generally result in transiti<strong>on</strong>alcosts, which are – as is perhaps to be expected (Flyvbjerg 2008)– almost always higher than anticipated (Vojnovic 1998). If the116


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birdtransiti<strong>on</strong> is towards a more efficient, effective, and accountable <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>, then the costs may be more than offset by the benefits.If not, transiti<strong>on</strong>al costs become an additi<strong>on</strong>al argument againstamalgamati<strong>on</strong>. One-time transiti<strong>on</strong> costs in Tor<strong>on</strong>to, for example,included acquisiti<strong>on</strong> of new technology for financial, humanresources, and payroll systems; renovati<strong>on</strong> of existing facilities suchas the Tor<strong>on</strong>to City Hall; and hiring of technical and professi<strong>on</strong>alexpertise with respect to areas such as telecommunicati<strong>on</strong>s (City ofTor<strong>on</strong>to 1999). In additi<strong>on</strong> to the <strong>on</strong>e-time costs, there are also costsassociated with staff exits.One of the major challenges of the Tor<strong>on</strong>to amalgamati<strong>on</strong> has beenthe amalgamati<strong>on</strong> of the seven previous administrati<strong>on</strong>s: “the keypost-amalgamati<strong>on</strong> problem has been leading and c<strong>on</strong>trolling the vastadministrative behemoth that the amalgamati<strong>on</strong> created” (Sanct<strong>on</strong>2004, 28). The task of integrating the operati<strong>on</strong>s and services of theseven <strong>municipal</strong>ities following amalgamati<strong>on</strong> was enormous andrequired the creati<strong>on</strong> of a new administrative and reporting structure,the implementati<strong>on</strong> of new informati<strong>on</strong> systems, the c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> ofcorporate services, real estate portfolios, and other functi<strong>on</strong>s, and theharm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> of human resources policies and classificati<strong>on</strong>s (Côté2009).Tax increases, or decreases?Three different questi<strong>on</strong>s may be asked about the effects ofamalgamati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxes. First, did taxes increase or decreaseas a result of the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>? Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, what was the effect ofthe amalgamati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> tax competiti<strong>on</strong> within the amalgamated area?And, thirdly, what was the effect <strong>on</strong> tax competiti<strong>on</strong> within the regi<strong>on</strong>as a whole, the GTA? As with cost savings, the data do not permitdefinitive answers to any of these questi<strong>on</strong>s but some things can besaid.117


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?Figure 5 Residential taxes per household, 1988–2008$2 500Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>to Scarborough Tor<strong>on</strong>toEast York North York YorkEtobicoke Metro Total Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>toLin. (Metro Total)Lin. (Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>to)$2 000$1 500$1 000$500$0198719881989199019911992199319941995199<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>997199819992000200120022003200420052006200720082009Figure 6 Business taxes per household, 1988–2008$1 800$1 600$1 400$1 200$1 000$800$600$400$200Metropolitan Tor<strong>on</strong>to Scarborough Tor<strong>on</strong>toEast York North York YorkEtobicoke Metro Total Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>toLin. (Metro Total)Lin. (Amalgamated Tor<strong>on</strong>to)$0198719881989199019911992199319941995199<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>997199819992000200120022003200420052006200720082009118


Enid Slack – Richard M. BirdThe first questi<strong>on</strong> is the easiest to answer: <strong>on</strong> the whole, taxesdeclined, particularly those <strong>on</strong> business property. Figures 5 and 6show residential and business property taxes per household in c<strong>on</strong>stant2008$ before and after amalgamati<strong>on</strong>. Prior to amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, it is notsurprising that residential property taxes per household were highestat the Metro level of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> since that level accounted for 70percent of total expenditures. Residential property taxes per householdwere next highest in the City of York, the poorest <strong>municipal</strong>ity inMetro and were generally lowest in Etobicoke and Scarborough.Although residential property taxes per household were generallydeclining prior to amalgamati<strong>on</strong> in the lower tier <strong>municipal</strong>ities, theywere rising in Metro. In 1998, residential property taxes increasedsharply because of the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services realignment menti<strong>on</strong>ed earlier.The downloading of some services to <strong>municipal</strong>ities coupledwith lower educati<strong>on</strong> property taxes (now levied by the province)resulted in higher <strong>municipal</strong> property taxes. Despite this importantchange, however, as Figure 5 shows residential property taxes inthe amalgamated city have declined slightly (in real terms) since1998, with the overall result that residential property taxes afteramalgamati<strong>on</strong> are not that dissimilar to what they would have beenin the absence of amalgamati<strong>on</strong>.Prior to amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, business property taxes per household weremuch higher in the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to than any of the other c<strong>on</strong>stituent<strong>municipal</strong>ities both because of the City’s much larger commercialand industrial tax base compared to the suburban <strong>municipal</strong>ities andto the higher tax rates applied in the city. Business property taxesfor the amalgamated city have fallen since 1998, reflecting boththe amalgamated city’s stated policy of reducing the tax burden<strong>on</strong> business and the way in which the complex and changing set ofprovincial rules governing property taxes have affected Tor<strong>on</strong>to(Bird, Slack and Tass<strong>on</strong>yi 2012).The other two questi<strong>on</strong>s are more difficult to answer. As menti<strong>on</strong>edearlier, Charlot, Paty and Piguet (2012) found in a study of Francethat reducing the number of <strong>municipal</strong>ities resulted in an increase intax rates. As Figure 6 shows, however, since amalgamati<strong>on</strong> resulted119


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?in lower rather than higher business property taxes in Tor<strong>on</strong>to (inreal terms per household), it appears that any effect from reducedcompetiti<strong>on</strong> for tax base within the metropolitan area has been morethan offset by other factors. One such factor seems to have beenthe increasingly str<strong>on</strong>g competiti<strong>on</strong> between the (expanded) City ofTor<strong>on</strong>to and other GTA regi<strong>on</strong>s and <strong>municipal</strong>ities. As Bird, Slack,and Tass<strong>on</strong>yi (2012, p, 196) c<strong>on</strong>clude, “changes in neighbouringjurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s emerge as <strong>on</strong>e of the most significant drivers of businessproperty tax rates in the GTA: yardstick competiti<strong>on</strong>, it seems, is aliveand well in the GTA.” In additi<strong>on</strong>, the same study notes (p.197) thatTor<strong>on</strong>to’s amalgamati<strong>on</strong> had significant negative effects <strong>on</strong> businessproperty tax rates not <strong>on</strong>ly in Tor<strong>on</strong>to (as shown in Figure 6) but alsoits most immediate (and most developed) neighbouring regi<strong>on</strong>s, Peeland York.GovernanceSome authors have argued that <strong>on</strong>e of the main failures ofamalgamati<strong>on</strong> has been the decline in active citizen participati<strong>on</strong>(Golden and Slack, 2006). Prior to the amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, the cityprovided many opportunities for citizen participati<strong>on</strong> (Tor<strong>on</strong>toTransiti<strong>on</strong> Team 1999): direct c<strong>on</strong>tact with politicians; deputati<strong>on</strong>sto committees of council and participati<strong>on</strong> in public c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> specific issues; opportunities for involvement in council subcommitteesand task forces; membership <strong>on</strong> <strong>municipal</strong> agencies,boards and commissi<strong>on</strong>s; involvement in partnerships, coaliti<strong>on</strong>s,and joint working groups am<strong>on</strong>g citizens, business groups, electedrepresentatives, and <strong>municipal</strong> staff; and community developmentinitiatives.Although governance processes remained transparent and accessibleafter amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Tor<strong>on</strong>to is definitely lessparticipatory than before amalgamati<strong>on</strong> (Côté 2009). The creati<strong>on</strong>of a much larger city has reduced the opportunities for citizeninvolvement. The creati<strong>on</strong> of community councils was designed,to some extent, to improve citizen access and participati<strong>on</strong>. Thecouncils were intended to be accessible to citizens and to provide120


Enid Slack – Richard M. Birda place where they could bring <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>cerns. In reality, however,community councils operate mostly as <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> planning committeesrather than as forums in which broader community issues can beaddressed (Golden and Slack 2006). In additi<strong>on</strong>, the councils almostinvariably address <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>ized and individual interests rather than citywideissues.The business community saw <strong>on</strong>e objective of amalgamati<strong>on</strong> ascreating a more effective entity for ec<strong>on</strong>omic development andmarketing (Stevens<strong>on</strong> and Gilbert 1999). Indeed, the Tor<strong>on</strong>to Boardof Trade str<strong>on</strong>gly supported the amalgamati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> these grounds. 40A larger <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> was thought to be more effective at promotingec<strong>on</strong>omic development by reducing bureaucracy and duplicati<strong>on</strong> andeliminating inter-<strong>municipal</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong>. In reality, as menti<strong>on</strong>edearlier, there is still duplicati<strong>on</strong> and the bureaucracy faces persistingproblems in merging both organizati<strong>on</strong>al cultures and such importantgovernance tools as z<strong>on</strong>ing bylaws. In additi<strong>on</strong>, as noted earlier,inter-<strong>municipal</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> between Tor<strong>on</strong>to and surrounding<strong>municipal</strong>ities persists.The amalgamati<strong>on</strong> led to further <strong>reform</strong>s in governance, most notablythe passage of a new City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to Act in 2006 which gave the citysomewhat greater authority and aut<strong>on</strong>omy than other <strong>municipal</strong>itiesin the province. In particular, the Act gives the City the power toimpose “direct taxes,” although as yet little has been d<strong>on</strong>e al<strong>on</strong>gthese lines. 41 This legislati<strong>on</strong> represented a fundamental shift in thetraditi<strong>on</strong>al relati<strong>on</strong>ship between the City and the Province, replacing40 The Tor<strong>on</strong>to Board of Trade is a voluntary organizati<strong>on</strong> with about 10,000members from the business community, including large and small businesses and individualmembers.41 This provisi<strong>on</strong> has a l<strong>on</strong>g list of exclusi<strong>on</strong>s, however: taxes cannot be imposed <strong>on</strong>income; <strong>on</strong> capital income; <strong>on</strong> sales of goods and services; <strong>on</strong> accommodati<strong>on</strong> (includinghotels/motels, apartments, clubs, etc.); <strong>on</strong> wealth (including inheritance); <strong>on</strong> machineryand equipment used in research and development or manufacturing or processing; <strong>on</strong> theacquisiti<strong>on</strong> of any gas or liquid that may be used for generating power by means of internalcombusti<strong>on</strong>; <strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> or use of energy (including electricity); <strong>on</strong> the generati<strong>on</strong>,exploitati<strong>on</strong>, extracti<strong>on</strong>, harvesting, processing, renewal, or transportati<strong>on</strong> of naturalresources; <strong>on</strong> the supply of natural gas or artificial gas; and <strong>on</strong> the use of highways withrespect to placing equipment under, <strong>on</strong>, or over the highway, The city is also excluded fromlevying a poll tax.121


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?the prescriptive framework with broad permissive powers for theCity. The Act recognized that the City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to was unique andgave it authority to negotiate directly with the federal <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>rather than going through the province as it had d<strong>on</strong>e in the pastand as other <strong>municipal</strong>ities still must (Côté 2009). A larger <strong>on</strong>e-tier<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> with more powers has allowed it to play a str<strong>on</strong>ger role<strong>on</strong> the regi<strong>on</strong>al, provincial, nati<strong>on</strong>al, and internati<strong>on</strong>al stage. In thelate 1990s, for example, Tor<strong>on</strong>to took the lead in bringing nati<strong>on</strong>alattenti<strong>on</strong> to the issue of homelessness and advocated for a new deal forcities nati<strong>on</strong>ally through the Federati<strong>on</strong> of Canadian Municipalitiesand the Big City Mayors’ Caucus (Côté 2009).Final observati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the Tor<strong>on</strong>to amalgamati<strong>on</strong>Studies leading up to the creati<strong>on</strong> of the new City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to allidentified problems of service coordinati<strong>on</strong> between MetropolitanTor<strong>on</strong>to and the other regi<strong>on</strong>s in the GTA. The creati<strong>on</strong> of the newcity was largely irrelevant to the problems faced both by Tor<strong>on</strong>to andby the GTA as a whole. Regi<strong>on</strong>al issues need regi<strong>on</strong>al soluti<strong>on</strong>s thatgo bey<strong>on</strong>d Tor<strong>on</strong>to’s boundaries. The problems currently facing thenew City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to are no less significant now than they were beforethe city was created; they have not been ameliorated by the creati<strong>on</strong>of the new city. At the same time, the amalgamated city has resultedin reduced access and participati<strong>on</strong> by residents in <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> decisi<strong>on</strong>making.Amalgamati<strong>on</strong> solved no problems. But it may, n<strong>on</strong>etheless, havehad some benefits, for example, a str<strong>on</strong>ger presence in ec<strong>on</strong>omicdevelopment, a fairer sharing of the tax base am<strong>on</strong>g rich and poor<strong>municipal</strong>ities, equalizing <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services so that every<strong>on</strong>e can enjoya similar level of services, and a str<strong>on</strong>ger voice for Tor<strong>on</strong>to withrespect to <strong>municipal</strong> issues within the regi<strong>on</strong> and across the provinceand country.122


Enid Slack – Richard M. Bird4.5 Are there less<strong>on</strong>s for Finland?If any less<strong>on</strong>s are to be learned from Tor<strong>on</strong>to, they would mainlyapply to Helsinki as the largest city in Finland. Even so, there aremany important differences between Tor<strong>on</strong>to and Helsinki rangingfrom size to the structure of governance and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> finance. Althoughboth cities account for about half of their regi<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>, Tor<strong>on</strong>tois much bigger: 2.5 milli<strong>on</strong> in a regi<strong>on</strong> of about 5 milli<strong>on</strong>, whileHelsinki is about 600,000 in a regi<strong>on</strong> of almost 1.4 milli<strong>on</strong>. Moreimportantly, Finland is a unitary country which decentralizes thedelivery of important social services to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level, while in Canadathose services are provided largely at the provincial level with <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s being resp<strong>on</strong>sible <strong>on</strong>ly for ‘<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>’ services. In Canada,<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s account for <strong>on</strong>ly 11.5 percent of public sectorexpenditure; in Finland, the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding ratio is over 40 percent.The differences are equally marked <strong>on</strong> the revenue side, with Finnish<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s financing 41 percent of their expenditures through(mainly) a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> income tax and <strong>on</strong>ly 2.5 percent from a property tax,while in Canada, <strong>municipal</strong>ities finance almost 50 percent of theirexpenditures through property taxes. Finally, although there is somecooperati<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g <strong>municipal</strong>ities in Canada with respect to a fewservices, <strong>municipal</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong> in Finland is much more developedand more important.The main reas<strong>on</strong>s for the current Finnish interest in mergers appearto be, first, to achieve ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale and, sec<strong>on</strong>d, to reduceproblems associated with relying <strong>on</strong> extensive inter-<strong>municipal</strong>cooperati<strong>on</strong>. It is possible that mergers may indeed enable somesmaller <strong>municipal</strong>ities (at least those that are in close proximity)to reap ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. It is unlikely, however, that any suchgains are to be reaped in the case of Helsinki. There may of coursebe other reas<strong>on</strong>s for c<strong>on</strong>sidering mergers in the metropolitan areasuch as addressing externalities, coordinating service delivery, landuse planning and transportati<strong>on</strong> for the regi<strong>on</strong>, and more equitablesharing of costs. Inter-<strong>municipal</strong> cooperati<strong>on</strong> may both make it harderto develop and implement a ‘regi<strong>on</strong>al’ visi<strong>on</strong> and be less clearlyaccountable since it is not always clear who is resp<strong>on</strong>sible. However,123


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?cooperative arrangements do both allow <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s to retainmore aut<strong>on</strong>omy and permit them to be more resp<strong>on</strong>sive to the wishesof <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents. On the whole, although the ‘two-tier’ approach hasits own problems, it may perhaps be the best way to rec<strong>on</strong>cile theec<strong>on</strong>omic and political problems inherent in devising an appropriategovernance structure for a metropolitan area such as Helsinki. Sucha structure may also perhaps be worth c<strong>on</strong>sidering as a more effectiveway to provide services in more scattered, sparsely populated (andoften aging) small communities elsewhere in the country (Kitchenand Slack 2006).124


Enid Slack – Richard M. BirdReferencesArretche, Marta (2012): Governance and Finance in Two Brazilian MetropolitanAreas, in Slack, Enid – Chattopadhyay, Rupak (eds.) Finance and Governance ofMetropolitan Areas in Federal Systems, Oxford University Press.Associati<strong>on</strong> of Finnish Local and Regi<strong>on</strong>al Authorities – Sutt<strong>on</strong>, Tyler (2011):Restructuring Local Government in Finland, Public Sector Digest, April 2011.Bahl, Roy (2010): Financing Metropolitan Cities in Local Government Financein (Draft ed.) The Challenges of the 21st Century, Sec<strong>on</strong>d Global Report <strong>on</strong>Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and Democracy, UCLG.Bahl, Roy – Linn, Johannes (1992): Urban Public Finance in Developing Countries,Oxford University Press.Barnett, Richard, R. (1997): Subsidiarity, Enabling Government, and LocalGovernance, in Hobs<strong>on</strong>, Paul A.R. – St-Hilaire, France (eds). Urban Governanceand Finance: A Case of Who Does What, The Institute for Research <strong>on</strong> PublicPolicy.Baumol, William J. (1967): Macroec<strong>on</strong>omics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomyof Urban Crisis, American Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review, 48 (3): 415–426.Berry, Christopher R. (2009): Imperfect Uni<strong>on</strong>: Representati<strong>on</strong> and Taxati<strong>on</strong> inMultilevel Governments, Cambridge University Press.Bird, Richard M. (1980): Central-Local Fiscal Relati<strong>on</strong>s and the Provisi<strong>on</strong> of UrbanPublic Services. Research M<strong>on</strong>ograph No. 30, Australian Nati<strong>on</strong>al UniversityPress for the Centre for Research <strong>on</strong> Federal Financial Relati<strong>on</strong>s.Bird, Richard M. (1995): Financing Local Services: Patterns, Problems, andPossibilities, Major Report 31, Centre for Urban and Community Studies,University of Tor<strong>on</strong>to, February.Bird, Richard M. – Slack, Enid (1993): Urban Public Finance in Canada, 2ndediti<strong>on</strong>, John Wiley and S<strong>on</strong>s.Bird, Richard M. – Slack, Enid (2008): Fiscal Aspects of Metropolitan Governance,in Rojas, E. – Cuadrado-Roura, J. – Guell, J. M. Governing the Metropolis:Principles and Case Studies (pp. 77–134). Inter-American Development Bank.Bird, Richard M. – Slack, Enid –Tass<strong>on</strong>yi, Almos (2012): A Tale of Two Taxes:Property Tax Reform in Ontario, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.Bish, Robert L. (2001): Local Government Amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s: Discredited 19thCentury Ideals Alive in the 21st, C. D. Howe Institute.125


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?Blom-Hansen, Jens (2010): Municipal Amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s and Comm<strong>on</strong> PoolProblems: The Danish Local Government Reform in 2007, ScandinavianPolitical Studies, 33(1): 51–73.Bosch, Núria – Espasa, Marta – Solé-Vilanova, Joaquim (2012): Governanceand Finance in Large Metropolitan Areas: The Case of Spain, in Slack, Enid –Chattopadhyay, Rupak (eds.) Finance and Governance of Metropolitan Areas inFederal Systems, Oxford University Press, forthcomingBoyne, George (1992): Local Government Structure and Performance: Less<strong>on</strong>sfrom America? Public Administrati<strong>on</strong>, 70: 333–57.Bret<strong>on</strong>, Albert (1996): Competitive Governments, Cambridge University Press.Byrnes, Joel – Dollery, Brian (2002): Do Ec<strong>on</strong>omies of Scale Exist in AustralianLocal Government? A Review of the Research Evidence, Urban Policy andResearch, 20:4, 391–414.Charlot, S. – Paty, S. – Piguet, V. (2012): Does Fiscal Cooperati<strong>on</strong> Increase LocalTax Rates in Urban Areas? Working Paper, Institut Nati<strong>on</strong>al de la RechercheAgr<strong>on</strong>omique.City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to (1999): Building the NEW City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to, Status Report <strong>on</strong>amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, January 1998–June 1999.Côté, André (2009): The Maturing Metropolis: Governance in Tor<strong>on</strong>to a Decade<strong>on</strong> from Amalgamati<strong>on</strong>, University of Tor<strong>on</strong>to, Institute <strong>on</strong> Municipal Financeand Governance (http://www.munkschool.utor<strong>on</strong>to.ca/imfg/uploads/92/the_maturing_metropolis_(andre_cote).pdf).Daffl<strong>on</strong>, Bernard (2012): Voluntary amalgamati<strong>on</strong> of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s: the Swissdebate in the European c<strong>on</strong>text, Working Paper. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Center for PublicPolicy.Dahlberg, Matz (2010): Local Government in Sweden in Moisio, Antti (ed.) LocalPublic Sector in Transiti<strong>on</strong>: A Nordic Perspective, Government Institute forEc<strong>on</strong>omic Research, Publicati<strong>on</strong>s 56, 122–154.Deloitte C<strong>on</strong>sulting (2001): Getting started: A review of the Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>toServices Board.Divay, Gérard – Wolfe, Jeanne with the collaborati<strong>on</strong> of Mario Polèse (2002):Metropolitan Governance Background Study: What Do We Need to Know?World Bank, December.Edwards, M. – Xiao, Y. (2009): Annexati<strong>on</strong>, Local Government Spending, and theComplicating Role of Density, Urban Affairs Review 45(2), 147–165.126


Enid Slack – Richard M. BirdFaguet, Jean-Paul (2004): Does Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> Increase GovernmentResp<strong>on</strong>siveness to Local Needs? Evidence from Bolivia, Journal of PublicEc<strong>on</strong>omics, 88 (3–4): 867–93.Faguet, Jean-Paul (2011): Decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and Governance, Ec<strong>on</strong>omicOrganisati<strong>on</strong> and Public Policy Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper Series No. 27, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong> Schoolof Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, June.Flyvbjerg, Bent (2008): Curbing Optimism Bias and Strategic Misrepresentati<strong>on</strong> inPlanning: Reference Class Forecasting in Practice. European Planning Studies,16 (1):3–21.Found, Adam (2012): Scale Ec<strong>on</strong>omies in Fire and Police Services. IMFG Paper inMunicipal Finance and Governance (forthcoming).Fox, William. F. – Gurley, Tami (2006): Will c<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> improve sub-nati<strong>on</strong>al<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s? Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC: World Bank.Frey, Bruno – Eichenberger, Reiner (1996): FOJC: Competitive Governments forEurope, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Review of Law and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 16 (3): 315–27.Frisken, Frances (1993): Planning and Servicing the Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to Area: TheInterplay of Provincial and Municipal Interests, in Rothblatt, D<strong>on</strong>ald N. – Sanct<strong>on</strong>,Andrew (eds.) Metropolitan Governance: American/Canadian Inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>alPerspectives, Institute of Governmental Studies Press, University of Californiaand Kingst<strong>on</strong>, Institute of Inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al Relati<strong>on</strong>s, Queen’s University.Gilbert, Guy (2011): Bey<strong>on</strong>d Inter-Municipal Partnerships Towards Two-TierMunicipalities: The Case of France, In IEB’s Report <strong>on</strong> Fiscal Federalism,28–37.Golden, Anne – Slack, Enid (2006): Urban Governance Reform in Tor<strong>on</strong>to: APreliminary Assessment, in Razin, Eran – Smith, Patrick (eds.) MetropolitanGoverning: Canadian Cases, Comparative Less<strong>on</strong>s, The Hebrew University ofJerusalem Magnes Press.GTA Task Force (1996): Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to, The Queen’s Printer.Hirsch, Werner Z. (1959): Expenditure Implicati<strong>on</strong>s of Metropolitan Growth andC<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong>, Review of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Statistics, 41, 232–41.Kitchen, Harry (1993): Efficient Delivery of Local Government Services,Government and Competitiveness Project, School of Policy Studies, Queen’sUniversity.Kitchen, Harry, M. (2002): Issues in Municipal Finance: Spending, Revenues,Governance, and Administrati<strong>on</strong>, Canadian Tax Foundati<strong>on</strong>.127


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?Kitchen, Harry M. – Slack, Enid (2006): Providing Public Services, in RemoteAreas in Bird, Richard M. – Vaillancourt, Francois (eds.) Perspectives <strong>on</strong> FiscalFederalism, World Bank Institute, pp. 123–139.Klink, Jeroen (2008): Recent Perspectives <strong>on</strong> Metropolitan Organizati<strong>on</strong>,Functi<strong>on</strong>s, and Governance, in Rojas, E. – Cuadrado-Roura J. – Guell, J. M.Governing the Metropolis: Principles and Case Studies (pp. 77–134), Inter-American Development Bank.KMPG (1996): Fresh Start: An Estimate of Potential Savings and Costs from theCreati<strong>on</strong> of a Single-Tier Local Government for Tor<strong>on</strong>to, A report prepared forthe Province of Ontario, December 16.Kübler, Daniel – Rochat, Philippe (2012): Governance and Finance in LargeMetropolitan Areas, in Federal Systems: Switzerland in Slack, Enid –Chattopadhyay, Rupak (eds.) Finance and Governance of Metropolitan Areas inFederal Systems, Oxford University Press, forthcomingKulisek, Larry – Price, Trevor (1988): Ontario Municipal Policy Affecting LocalAut<strong>on</strong>omy: A Case Study Involving Windsor and Tor<strong>on</strong>to, Urban HistoryReview, 16 (3).Kushner, Joseph – Siegel, David (2005): Are Services Delivered More Efficientlyafter Municipal Amalgamati<strong>on</strong>s? Canadian Public Administrati<strong>on</strong>, 48(2):251–67.Lefèvre, Christian (2008): Democratic Governability of Metropolitan Areas:Internati<strong>on</strong>al Experiences and Less<strong>on</strong>s for Latin American cities, in Rojas,Eduardo – Cuadrado, Juan R. – Guell, J. M. Governing the Metropolis: Principlesand Case Studies, Inter-American Development Bank.Locke, Wade – Tass<strong>on</strong>yi, Almos (1993): Shared tax bases and <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public sectorexpenditure decisi<strong>on</strong>s, Canadian Tax Journal, 41: 941–957.Moisio, Antti (2011a): Choosing between Regulati<strong>on</strong> and Local Self-Government:The Finnish Case, Paper prepared for Copenhagen Workshop <strong>on</strong> NormativeFrameworks of Decentralisati<strong>on</strong> and Inter-<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al Fiscal Relati<strong>on</strong>s:Efficient Instruments for Desired Balance between Decentralisati<strong>on</strong> and Merit,Danish Ministry of the Interior and Health and Korean Institute of Public Finance.Moisio, Antti (2011b): Municipal Partnerships: The Experience of Nordic Countries.In IEB’s Report <strong>on</strong> Fiscal Federalism, Institut d’Ec<strong>on</strong>omia de Barcel<strong>on</strong>a, 20–27.Moisio, Antti – Loikkanen, Heikki A. – Oulasvirta, Lasse (2010): Public Servicesat the Local Level – The Finnish Way, Government Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omicResearch, Policy Reports 2.128


Enid Slack – Richard M. BirdOECD (2006): Competitive Cities in the Global Ec<strong>on</strong>omy. OECD.Sanct<strong>on</strong>, Andrew (1993): Local Government Reorganizati<strong>on</strong> in Canada since 1975.Inter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al Committee <strong>on</strong> Urban and Regi<strong>on</strong>al Research, Tor<strong>on</strong>to.Sanct<strong>on</strong>, Andrew (1994): Governing Canada’s City-Regi<strong>on</strong>s: Adapting Form toFuncti<strong>on</strong>, M<strong>on</strong>treal: The Institute for Research <strong>on</strong> Public Policy.Sanct<strong>on</strong>, Andrew (1996): Reducing Costs by C<strong>on</strong>solidating Municipalities: NewBrunswick, Nova Scotia, and Ontario, Canadian Public Administrati<strong>on</strong> 39 (3):267–89.Sanct<strong>on</strong>, Andrew (2004): Bey<strong>on</strong>d the Municipal: Governance for Canadian Cities,Policy Opti<strong>on</strong>s.Schwartz, Harvey (2004): The Relevance of Tor<strong>on</strong>to’s New GovernmentalStructure for the 21st Century, Canadian Journal of Regi<strong>on</strong>al Science, 27(1).Sharpe, Laurence J. (ed.) (1995): The Future of Metropolitan Government. In TheGovernment of World Cities: The Future of the Metro Model, John Wiley &S<strong>on</strong>s Ltd.Slack, Enid (2000): A Preliminary Assessment of the New City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to,Canadian Journal of Regi<strong>on</strong>al Science, 18(1).Slack, Enid (2005): Assessing Municipal Amalgamati<strong>on</strong> in Tor<strong>on</strong>to, Canada: WhatHas it Achieved? Nati<strong>on</strong>al Security and Defence, No. 11, Ukrainian Centre forEc<strong>on</strong>omic and Political Studies, Razumkov Centre.Slack, Enid – Chattopadhyay, Rupak (2009): Finance and Governance of CapitalCities in Federal Systems, M<strong>on</strong>treal & Kingst<strong>on</strong>: McGill-Queen’s UniversityPress.Slack, Enid – Chattopadhyay, Rupak (2012): Finance and Governance ofMetropolitan Areas in Federal Systems, Oxford University Press.Smart, Michael (1998): Taxati<strong>on</strong> and Deadweight Loss in a System ofInter<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>al Transfers, Canadian Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, 31 (February):186–206.Stevens<strong>on</strong>, D<strong>on</strong> – Gilbert, Richard (1999): Restructuring Municipal Government inGreater Tor<strong>on</strong>to: Amalgamati<strong>on</strong> to Form the New City of Tor<strong>on</strong>to and Creati<strong>on</strong>of the Greater Tor<strong>on</strong>to Services Board, 1996-1999. Paper prepared for the Cityof M<strong>on</strong>treal, July 16.Steytler, Nico (2012): Governance and Finance of Two South African MetropolitanAreas, in Slack, Enid – Chattopadhyay, Rupak (eds.) Finance and Governance ofMetropolitan Areas in Federal Systems, Oxford University Press.129


Merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities: Is bigger better?Stren, Richard – Camer<strong>on</strong>, Robert (2005): Metropolitan governance <strong>reform</strong>: anintroducti<strong>on</strong>, Public Administrati<strong>on</strong> and Development, 25 (4).Tindal, Richard, C. (1996): Municipal restructuring: the myth and the reality,Municipal World, March.Tor<strong>on</strong>to Transiti<strong>on</strong> Team (1997): New City, New Opportunities – Interim Report,Tor<strong>on</strong>to.Vojnovic, Igor (1998): Municipal C<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong> in the 1990s: An Analysis of BritishColumbia, New Brunswick, and Nova Scotia, Canadian Public Administrati<strong>on</strong>,41(2).130


Chapter 5Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergers 1Tuukka SaarimaaGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic ResearchJanne TukiainenGovernment Institute for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Researchand Helsinki Center of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research5.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong>In most countries, the producti<strong>on</strong> and funding of many public servicesis decentralized to <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s or <strong>municipal</strong>ities. This type ofdecentralizati<strong>on</strong> raises two important and often intertwined questi<strong>on</strong>sthat need to be answered. The first is the questi<strong>on</strong> of assignment offuncti<strong>on</strong>s and revenue sources to different levels of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>. 2According to classic arguments by Musgrave (1959) and Oates(1972), in the absence of scale benefits in the provisi<strong>on</strong> of a publicgood or service and interjurisdicti<strong>on</strong>al spillovers, decisi<strong>on</strong> makingshould be decentralized so that public good provisi<strong>on</strong> can be matchedto heterogeneous preferences of the voter populati<strong>on</strong>.The sec<strong>on</strong>d questi<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cerns the optimal size of <strong>municipal</strong>ities<strong>on</strong>ce the assignment of tasks and taxes has been settled. In theory, theoptimal size of <strong>municipal</strong>ities is determined as a tradeoff of opposing1 We thank Essi Eerola, Jani-Petri Laamanen, Antti Moisio and Heikki Pursiainenfor helpful comments. We also thank seminar participants at the PEARL c<strong>on</strong>ference inHelsinki and at <strong>VATT</strong> for useful discussi<strong>on</strong>s. Oskari Harjunen provided excellent researchassistance. Janne Tukiainen is grateful to the Emil Aalt<strong>on</strong>en Foundati<strong>on</strong> for financial support.2 See Oates (1999) for an overview of this literature.131


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersforces. On the <strong>on</strong>e hand, ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale and interjurisdicti<strong>on</strong>alspillovers from <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public services favor large <strong>municipal</strong>ities. On theother hand, as the size of a <strong>municipal</strong>ity increases so does preferenceheterogeneity am<strong>on</strong>g the voters making it more difficult to tailor theservices to match voter preferences (Alesina and Spolaore 1997 and2003). 3 A related result by Tiebout (1956) offers decentralizati<strong>on</strong> asa tool for efficient pricing of <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods in a world wheremobile households shop for a suitable tax and public good bundleoffered by <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Fewer and larger <strong>municipal</strong>ities meanthat citizen-voters have fewer choices and <strong>municipal</strong>ities face lesscompetiti<strong>on</strong>, which may lead to a situati<strong>on</strong> where Tiebout’s resultdoes not hold. 4The above arguments make it clear that the size and number of<strong>municipal</strong>ities is a key policy decisi<strong>on</strong> in achieving a welfaremaximizing producti<strong>on</strong> of decentralized public services. Furthermore,for a variety of dynamic reas<strong>on</strong>s, such as migrati<strong>on</strong>, different trendsin aging and advances in producti<strong>on</strong> technology of public services,<strong>municipal</strong>ity borders need to be redrawn occasi<strong>on</strong>ally whilec<strong>on</strong>sidering the above arguments.Recently there has been a wave of <strong>municipal</strong>ity mergers in Finland. 5Until now, the mergers have been voluntary and decided independentlyat the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level by <strong>municipal</strong> councils. However, the new coaliti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> that came to power after the 2011 parliamentaryelecti<strong>on</strong>s has a clear view that more mergers are necessary andeven forced mergers, similar to Danish <strong>reform</strong> in 2007, are beingdiscussed. 6 Not surprisingly, this policy has raised oppositi<strong>on</strong> fromboth <strong>municipal</strong> politicians and citizens.3 There are other reas<strong>on</strong>s for <strong>municipal</strong> mergers raised in the Finnish c<strong>on</strong>texts. Oneexample is <strong>municipal</strong> risk management. In the absence of <strong>municipal</strong> insurance markets orjoint liability, the ec<strong>on</strong>omy of a small <strong>municipal</strong>ity may be threatened by a single citizenwith a costly disease.4 Naturally, the Tiebout model is unrealistic in many ways. See Boadway andTremblay (2012) for a recent review of the model.5 Saarimaa and Tukiainen (2012) present empirical evidence <strong>on</strong> what <strong>municipal</strong>characteristics are associated with these merger decisi<strong>on</strong>s. They also present a more detaileddescripti<strong>on</strong> of the merger process.6 Forced mergers are technically possible even today.132


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne TukiainenThe public arguments opposing mergers in Finland usually referto diminishing <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> and an increasing mismatch ofvoter preferences and implemented policy. 7 The usual argument isas follows. In larger <strong>municipal</strong>ities, relatively small interest groupsfind it increasingly difficult to elect a politician that represents theirinterests into a positi<strong>on</strong> of power. For example, a merger involvinga small <strong>municipal</strong>ity and a large <strong>municipal</strong>ity will most likely result(after the next electi<strong>on</strong>s) in a new council, where <strong>on</strong>ly a few (if any)councilors are citizens of the smaller <strong>municipal</strong>ity. As mergers arepartly motivated by ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale, it is likely that a merger willresult in restructuring of public services, perhaps by c<strong>on</strong>centratingthe provisi<strong>on</strong> of services to densely populated areas. A councilor thatis originally from the small <strong>municipal</strong>ity is likely to defend <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>services because her voters and the councilor herself prefer them. Wewill discuss this issue at length in Secti<strong>on</strong> 5.2.The purpose of this paper is to analyze empirically whether voterstruly value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> and whether they vote strategically (asopposed to voting sincerely) in order to obtain a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representative.To be more specific, we analyze how voters reacted to the recent<strong>municipal</strong>ity merger wave in Finland using data from two <strong>municipal</strong>electi<strong>on</strong>s, before and after the merger wave. Our analysis is possibledue to a unique individual candidate and polling district leveldata. Using these data we can decompose a merged <strong>municipal</strong>ityinto the original pre-merger <strong>municipal</strong>ities and trace back the votedistributi<strong>on</strong>s of candidates at the pre-merger <strong>municipal</strong> level. Thesedata facilitate difference-in-differences (DID) analysis where theunit of observati<strong>on</strong> is the old <strong>municipal</strong>ity and voting data comefrom electi<strong>on</strong>s before and after the merger wave. If voters value<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>, we should observe a strategic resp<strong>on</strong>se fromthe voters to fiercer competiti<strong>on</strong> in the next electi<strong>on</strong> so that theypool votes to candidates in the old <strong>municipal</strong>ities. While there is avast literature showing that households value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> services, to ourknowledge, this is the first paper to offer plausible causal evidence7 Naturally, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> politicians are also c<strong>on</strong>cerned about their re-electi<strong>on</strong> becausemergers reduce the number of available council seats and change the set of candidatesrunning for the same seats. See Hyytinen, Saarimaa and Tukiainen (2012) for details andempirical evidence.133


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersc<strong>on</strong>cerning references for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> that uses actual votingdata, instead of survey or house price data. 8We find that voters in <strong>municipal</strong>ities that underwent a merger pooltheir votes to str<strong>on</strong>g candidates compared to voters in <strong>municipal</strong>itiesthat did not merge. Moreover, we find that this effect is heterogeneouswith respect to the relative size of the merged <strong>municipal</strong>ities andtheir geographic distance. In smaller merged <strong>municipal</strong>ities, thepooling effect is much larger than in the larger merger partners. Theheterogeneity in the effect is even clearer with respect to distancebetween the merger partners’ <strong>municipal</strong> centers. 9 Moreover, whenwe analyze distance and populati<strong>on</strong> heterogeneity jointly, we findthat <strong>on</strong>ly distance matters. This implies that the locati<strong>on</strong> of servicesis the main reas<strong>on</strong> behind strategic voting. We also find that votersc<strong>on</strong>centrate votes <strong>on</strong>ly within parties. This means that while <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>representati<strong>on</strong> is important, voters are not willing to cross party linesin order to guarantee <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>. Finding that the locati<strong>on</strong>of services is important for citizens is hardly a surprise, but it is verysurprising and important that other dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of heterogeneity d<strong>on</strong>ot seem to matter.This result is useful in two respects. First, while the evidence <strong>on</strong>the importance of preference heterogeneity as a determinant of<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> formati<strong>on</strong> is str<strong>on</strong>g (Brasingt<strong>on</strong> 2003a and 2003b,Alesina Baqir and Hoxby 2004, Gord<strong>on</strong> and Knight 2009, Weese2011 and Saarimaa and Tukiainen 2012), we c<strong>on</strong>tribute to thisliterature by further dissecting the different channels through whichpreference heterogeneity am<strong>on</strong>g voters may influence <strong>municipal</strong>decisi<strong>on</strong>-making. More precisely, we show that voters’ preferencesover the locati<strong>on</strong> of public services are the main reas<strong>on</strong> why votersvalue <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>. While we are quite c<strong>on</strong>fident that this resultis causal and internally valid (the result applies to the <strong>municipal</strong>itiesthat actually merged), external validity of the result is an open8 A typical approach in the literature has been to show that the quality ofneighborhood services capitalizes to house values. See e.g. Black and Machin (2011) andthe references therein.9 Municipal center is simply defined as the town or city hall where the <strong>municipal</strong>council meets.134


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainenissue. It could be, for example, that voters in the <strong>municipal</strong>ities thatended up merging have more homogenous preferences than votersin <strong>municipal</strong>ities that did not merge. 10 N<strong>on</strong>etheless, if the central<str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> is going to force mergers <strong>on</strong> <strong>municipal</strong>ities, <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>representati<strong>on</strong> and the locati<strong>on</strong> of public services should be am<strong>on</strong>gthe key issues that need to be resolved in the process.Sec<strong>on</strong>d, this paper c<strong>on</strong>tributes to the large literature <strong>on</strong> strategicvoting. 11 Both ec<strong>on</strong>omists and political scientists have been forl<strong>on</strong>g interested in whether voters vote sincerely (always vote theirpreferred candidate) or strategically (vote some<strong>on</strong>e else than theirpreferred candidate, because it is optimal <strong>on</strong>ce accounting forexpectati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cerning other voters’ behavior). This distincti<strong>on</strong>is fundamental for the understanding of the democratic process ingeneral, formulating theoretical models in political ec<strong>on</strong>omy anddesigning electi<strong>on</strong> mechanisms. Despite the massive theoretical (e.g.Besley and Coate 1997 and Myatt 2007) and empirical (e.g. Cain1978, Cox 1998 and Karp et al. 2002) literature <strong>on</strong> the topic, crediblecausal evidence is scant. To our knowledge, the <strong>on</strong>ly existing causaltest of strategic voting theory is by Fujiwara (2011), who usesregressi<strong>on</strong> disc<strong>on</strong>tinuity design and finds causal evidence in favor ofDuverger’s law. 12 Our paper can be seen as a causal test of strategicbehavior of voters as we basically ask whether voters desert theirpreferred <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidate in order to guarantee <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> inthe post-merger council.The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In secti<strong>on</strong> 5.2, weraise some theoretical arguments <strong>on</strong> why <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>may matter to voters. Secti<strong>on</strong> 5.3 presents a short overview of theinstituti<strong>on</strong>al setting of Finland with respect to the role and natureof <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s, electi<strong>on</strong> mechanisms and the merger process.In Secti<strong>on</strong> 5.4, we describe our data and formulate our empirical10 The results from Saarimaa and Tukiainen (2012) support this claim.11 Lyytikäinen and Tukiainen (2012) show using regressi<strong>on</strong> disc<strong>on</strong>tinuity design thatvoters in Finnish <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong>s are rati<strong>on</strong>al, i.e. they account for the probability oftheir vote affecting electi<strong>on</strong> outcomes when they decide whether to vote or abstain. Giventhat these voters are rati<strong>on</strong>al, it makes sense to ask whether they are also strategic.12 Duwerger’s law asserts that a plurality rule electi<strong>on</strong> system (or first past the postrule) tends to favor a two-party system over multipartyism because of strategic voting.135


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersstrategy. We show some descriptive graphs in Secti<strong>on</strong> 5.5 and theactual results in Secti<strong>on</strong> 5.6, including how reliable the results are.Secti<strong>on</strong> 5.7 c<strong>on</strong>cludes.5.2 Why <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> matters?In this secti<strong>on</strong>, we sketch some theoretical arguments why votersmay value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>, especially after a <strong>municipal</strong> merger.The arguments raised here are not meant to be formal or exhaustive.Rather they serve as motivati<strong>on</strong> for our empirical analysis in thesubsequent secti<strong>on</strong>s.In general, voters may benefit from having a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representative inthe council for (at least) four reas<strong>on</strong>s. First, if households with similarpreferences have a tendency to sort into same <strong>municipal</strong>ities (orneighborhoods) as suggested by Tiebout (1956), a councilor livingclose to a voter is more likely to share the preferences of the voterin terms of the service-tax bundle provided by the <strong>municipal</strong>ity. 13 Ifthere are costs related to the distance between a voter and a candidatein acquiring informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the preferences of candidates, voting fora <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidate becomes desirable.The sec<strong>on</strong>d reas<strong>on</strong> why <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> may be important isrelated to the comm<strong>on</strong> pool problem presented by Weingast, Shepsleand Johnsen (1981). If there are identifiable (geographic) <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> groupswithin a <strong>municipal</strong>ity that benefit from spending in their area and ifthe spending is financed globally by all taxpayers in the <strong>municipal</strong>ity,having a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representative may be instrumental in receiving thebenefits from <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending. Clearly, the citizens of pre-merger<strong>municipal</strong>ities can be seen as representing different <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> groups.Third, if councilors and voters c<strong>on</strong>sume similar services and disliketravel costs, a councilor living close to a voter is more likely toshare the voter’s preferences over the geographic locati<strong>on</strong> of publicservices (schools, basic health care centers etc.). Furthermore, since13 See e.g. Bayer et al. (2007) and Bayer and McMillan (2012) <strong>on</strong> the importance ofsorting according neighborhood quality and observable household characteristics.136


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainenhouse values are tied to the prevalence and quality of (public) servicesin the neighborhood, house value becomes an incentive device thatmay align councilors’ and voters’ preferences. This can be easily seenwhen both the councilor and the voter are homeowners. In this case,both want to promote policies that increase their house value. 14 Thecloser the councilor lives to the voter, the more correlated their housevalues are, and because of this, the more aligned are the incentivesof the councilor with the voter’s preferences. Moreover, both partiesdo not have to be homeowners in order for this incentive mechanismto work. For example, a voter with school-aged children may bemore likely to vote for a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> homeowner councilor without childrenthan a councilor with children that lives in another neighborhood.The logic is that the homeowner councilor has incentives to promoteinvestments into the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> school because it makes the neighborhoodmore attractive and raises neighborhood house prices. 15In some cases voters face a tradeoff between voting for a candidatethat shares her preferences over the service-tax bundle and voting fora <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidate. This happens when sorting is imperfect and a votersimply does not have a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidate that shares her preferences.That is, a voter’s preferred candidate in terms of the service-tax bundlelives in another neighborhood. Furthermore, this tradeoff is a functi<strong>on</strong>of neighborhood populati<strong>on</strong> so that electing a <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representativeis harder in smaller neighborhoods. In this case, voters from thesetypes of neighborhoods may have incentives to vote strategically (asoppose to voting sincerely) and c<strong>on</strong>centrate their votes for a single (orfew) <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidate even when this candidate is not the first choicefor all of the voters. Municipal mergers create plausibly exogenousvariati<strong>on</strong> in the set of voters who face this tradeoff and how, in asense, large this tradeoff is.Finally, jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> size may have a direct effect <strong>on</strong> voting behavior.For example, Dahl and Tufte (1973) argue that as jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> sizeincreases voters’ beliefs about their competence in understanding and14 See e.g. DiPasquale and Glaeser (1999).15 For example, Hilber and Mayer (2008) find empirical evidence that evenhouseholds without children promote investments into <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> schools because the investmentsraise their house values. See also Fischel (2001).137


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergerstaking part in politics weakens. 16 Recently, Lassen and Serritzlew(2011) find using DID methods and the Danish <strong>municipal</strong>ity <strong>reform</strong> of2007, that jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> size has a sizeable negative effect <strong>on</strong> citizens’beliefs in this respect, as perceived in a citizen survey. Turnout maydiminish in <strong>municipal</strong>ities that undergo a merger due to an increase inpopulati<strong>on</strong> size and the effect should be larger in small <strong>municipal</strong>itiesas they experience a relatively larger populati<strong>on</strong> increase. Reducedturnout would make pooling of votes even more crucial for thosewho vote in small <strong>municipal</strong>ities.5.3 Instituti<strong>on</strong>al backgroundLocal <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>s play an important role in the ec<strong>on</strong>omies of manycountries. In Finland, public goods and services are provided by twotiers of <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> where <strong>municipal</strong>ities c<strong>on</strong>stitute the <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> level. 17Because of the variety of tasks assigned to them, <strong>municipal</strong>ities areof c<strong>on</strong>siderable importance to the whole ec<strong>on</strong>omy. The GDP share of<strong>municipal</strong>ity spending is roughly 18 percent and they employ around20 percent of the total workforce. The bulk of Finnish <strong>municipal</strong>ities’expenditures come from producing social and health care servicesand primary educati<strong>on</strong>. In most of these services, in additi<strong>on</strong> tocosts, quantity and quality, also the locati<strong>on</strong> should be relevant forthe citizens. Municipalities fund their spending mostly through theirown revenue sources. The most important revenue source is the flat<strong>municipal</strong> income tax which the <strong>municipal</strong>ities can set freely. Dueto extensive tasks and power in setting taxes, <strong>municipal</strong> councilsare relatively powerful compared to <strong>municipal</strong>ities in many othercountries. An extensive central <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g> grant system is used toequalize <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> cost and revenue disparities.The number of <strong>municipal</strong>ities in Finland has diminished c<strong>on</strong>siderablysince the 1940’s as can be seen from Figure 1. In the 1960’s almost16 In political science this is coined as political efficacy. It can be further divided intointernal and external efficacy. The former refers to citizens’ beliefs that they are competentto understand and take part in politics and the latter to whether their participati<strong>on</strong> may havean effect <strong>on</strong> policy outcomes.17 See Moisio et al. (2010) for details.138


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainenall and in the 2000’s all of the mergers have been voluntary. Besidesthe two merger waves, <strong>municipal</strong>ity structure has been quite stablethrough time. In this paper, we analyze mergers that took place betweenthe 2004 and 2008 <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong>s. Between these two electi<strong>on</strong>s,there were 47 <strong>municipal</strong> mergers involving 130 <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Thenumber of <strong>municipal</strong>ities in a given merger ranged from 2 to up to 10<strong>municipal</strong>ities.Figure 1 Number of <strong>municipal</strong>ities in Finland, 1917–2010Number of <strong>municipal</strong>ities350 400 450 500 550 6001920 1940 1960 1980 2000 2020YearMergers between <strong>municipal</strong>ities are voluntary and the <strong>municipal</strong>itycouncils are allowed to decide which potential mergers they c<strong>on</strong>sider.A typical merger process is as follows: After an initial feasibility study,the <strong>municipal</strong> boards make a proposal of the merger to the <strong>municipal</strong>councils. This proposal is voted <strong>on</strong> by the councils. In about half thecases, the potential merger includes more than two <strong>municipal</strong>ities. Ifthe proposed merger gains a majority in all the participating councils,139


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersthe merger goes through. If not, it is cancelled and the <strong>municipal</strong>itiesc<strong>on</strong>tinue as they were.Finland has a multi-party system and currently there are eight partiesin the Finnish parliament and these parties also dominate <strong>municipal</strong>politics. In the 2004 <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong>s the three largest parties(the Centre Party, the Social Democrats and the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Coaliti<strong>on</strong>)received roughly 68 percent of the votes with roughly similar shares. 18In additi<strong>on</strong> to the traditi<strong>on</strong>al left- and right-wing divisi<strong>on</strong> (roughly theSocial Democrats and the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Coaliti<strong>on</strong>), a somewhat peculiarfeature of the Finnish political landscape is the str<strong>on</strong>g support for theCentre Party (formerly known as the Agrarian League).Municipal council size is a step functi<strong>on</strong> of <strong>municipal</strong>ity’s populati<strong>on</strong>and is determined by law. The council size functi<strong>on</strong> is as follows: 13or 15 for 2000 or less, 21 for 2,001–4,000; 27 for 4,001–8,000; 35 for8,001–15,000; 43 for 15,001–30,000; 51 for 30,001–60,000; 59 for60,001–120,000; 67 for 120,001–250,000; 75 for 250,001–400,000and 85 for over 400,000. The maximum number of candidates foreach party is 1.5 times the legally determined council size. So, inadditi<strong>on</strong> to reduced council size, a merger may also lead to a reducednumber of candidates for a given party.Each <strong>municipal</strong>ity has <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e electoral district (i.e. c<strong>on</strong>stituency)and no geographic quotas are in place. This applies also to themerged <strong>municipal</strong>ities. However, most <strong>municipal</strong>ities have manypolling districts, which simply define the locati<strong>on</strong> where people go tovote (e.g. <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> school). The electi<strong>on</strong> data is registered and publiclyavailable at the polling district and candidate level (also votes givenin advance are registered to the correct polling district). Since thesepolling districts do not change because of the mergers, we know thelocati<strong>on</strong> of voters also after the mergers. That is, even though we d<strong>on</strong>ot know the addresses of the candidates, knowing the locati<strong>on</strong> of thevotes facilitates our empirical analysis of strategic voting.18 In the 2011 parliamentary electi<strong>on</strong>, the Finns Party became the third largest partyin the parliament overtaking the Centre Party.140


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne TukiainenThe Finnish <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong>s use the open-list method. Thisaspect is crucial for our analysis because voters vote not <strong>on</strong>ly forthe party, but for the individual candidates. Thus, they can influencethe positi<strong>on</strong> of their <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidate <strong>on</strong> the party list even afterthe merger. However, parties act as gatekeepers and choosethe candidates. This may c<strong>on</strong>found our analysis, because if <strong>on</strong>ly few<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidates from smaller <strong>municipal</strong>ities make it to the postmergerlists, the observed change in c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> after the merger insmall <strong>municipal</strong>ities may not be due to strategic voting, but simplydue to changes in the set of candidates. We can address this issue to acertain extent in the subsequent analysis.5.4 Data and empirical strategyDataOur main data source is the electi<strong>on</strong> database maintained bythe Ministry of Justice. 19 We have data <strong>on</strong> votes received byindividual candidates from two <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong>s held in Octoberof 2004 and 2008. The 2008 <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong>s were held usingthe new merged <strong>municipal</strong>ities as c<strong>on</strong>stituencies. 20 The novel feature ofour data is that they include informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> polling districts within a<strong>municipal</strong>ity. That is, we observe the number of votes coming fromdifferent polling districts for each candidate. The number of pollingdistricts varies between <strong>municipal</strong>ities, but the important thingfor our purposes is that polling districts are used <strong>on</strong>ly for vote countingand voting locati<strong>on</strong> purposes and there are no quotas in <strong>municipal</strong>councils based <strong>on</strong> the polling district divisi<strong>on</strong>.Since <strong>municipal</strong>ities are divided into (time invariant) pollingdistricts we can build a panel data set where the cross-secti<strong>on</strong>alunits are the <strong>municipal</strong>ities in 2004, i.e. before the mergers. 21 That19 Similar data are also freely available <strong>on</strong>line at Statistics Finland’s website.20 In some cases, the <strong>municipal</strong>ities merged officially at the start of 2009. However,also in these cases the new <strong>municipal</strong>ity divisi<strong>on</strong> was used in the 2008 electi<strong>on</strong>s.21 In some cases, the polling districts changed and we were unable to trace back theold <strong>municipal</strong> divisi<strong>on</strong>. In these cases, we drop the entire merger from the analysis.141


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersis, we can trace back which candidates received votes from the premerger<strong>municipal</strong>ities also in the post-merger electi<strong>on</strong>s in 2008. Ourcomparis<strong>on</strong> would not be possible if we would <strong>on</strong>ly observe thenumber of votes for each candidate at the <strong>municipal</strong> level. If thiswere the case, we could not trace back which votes actually camefrom different parts of a given merger.Ec<strong>on</strong>ometric modelWe analyze strategic voting behavior using a DID strategy.The simplest specificati<strong>on</strong> that we use can be written as(1) y = α0 + α1treated + α2after + α3 treated ⋅ after + u ,it i it i it itwhere y itis the outcome in questi<strong>on</strong> for <strong>municipal</strong>ity i (2004 divisi<strong>on</strong>)in year t, treated a dummy variable that equals <strong>on</strong>e if the <strong>municipal</strong>ityunderwent a merger between the two electi<strong>on</strong>s, after a dummy variablethat equals <strong>on</strong>e if the data come from post-merger electi<strong>on</strong>s and u isthe error term. In this setup, if a merger changes voter behavior, weshould find that α 3differs statistically from zero.Furthermore, if voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>, we should observevoters from small <strong>municipal</strong>ities in a given merger to c<strong>on</strong>centratetheir votes more than voters from larger <strong>municipal</strong>ities simplybecause smaller <strong>municipal</strong>ities have a lower chance of electingrepresentatives to the post-merger council. To test this hypothesis weestimate the following regressi<strong>on</strong>(2)y = β + β treated + β popdiff + β after + β treated ⋅afterit 0 1 i 2 i 3 it 4 i itβ5 treatedi afterit popdiffi uit,+ ⋅ ⋅ +where popdiff is the difference between a <strong>municipal</strong>ity’s populati<strong>on</strong>and the populati<strong>on</strong> of the largest <strong>municipal</strong>ity in the group of<strong>municipal</strong>ities that took part in the same merger. The populati<strong>on</strong> ismeasured <strong>on</strong>ly in 2004 (we observe 2008 <strong>municipal</strong> populati<strong>on</strong>s142


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainen<strong>on</strong>ly at the merger level). The variable popdiff is defined <strong>on</strong>ly for<strong>municipal</strong>ities that underwent a merger, because we do not haveany merger partners for the c<strong>on</strong>trol group. Furthermore, the popdiffvariable is zero for the largest <strong>municipal</strong>ities in a given merger group.This specificati<strong>on</strong> is similar to the difference-in-difference-indifferencesestimator with the excepti<strong>on</strong> that popdiff is c<strong>on</strong>tinuousand does not vary within the c<strong>on</strong>trol group or over time. 22 Thus,we cannot fully saturate the model with respect to the pair wiseinteracti<strong>on</strong>s of all the right hand side variables. More precisely, theexcluded interacti<strong>on</strong> treated*popdiff equals popdiff, and thus, popdiffc<strong>on</strong>trols for both. Potentially more problematic is the exclusi<strong>on</strong>of the interacti<strong>on</strong> variable popdiff*after, because it equals thetreated*popdiff*after variable. Thus, our main parameter of interestcaptures a joint effect. In theory this is an issue, but not in practice.Municipal populati<strong>on</strong>s do not change much over the 4 years and thereis no reas<strong>on</strong> to assume that changes in popdiff would have any effect<strong>on</strong> voting behavior independent of the merger. Therefore, we canc<strong>on</strong>clude that if the parameter β 5differs statistically from zero, votersfrom smaller <strong>municipal</strong>ities react differently to mergers compared tovoters from larger <strong>municipal</strong>ities.The sec<strong>on</strong>d aspect of within merger heterogeneity that we analyzec<strong>on</strong>cerns party preferences. To this end, we estimate the followingmodely = γ + γ treated + γ diffparty + γ after + γ treated ⋅after(3)it 0 1 i 2 i 3 it 4 i it+ γ5treatedi ⋅afterit ⋅ diffpartyi + uit,where diffparty equals <strong>on</strong>e if a <strong>municipal</strong>ity had a different largestparty in the 2004 elected councils than the largest <strong>municipal</strong>ity inthe same merger and zero otherwise. For the largest <strong>municipal</strong>ity ina merger, diffparty is equal to zero. If party preferences matter, weshould find that γ 5is statistically significant and most likely positive.That is, voters from a smaller merger partner with different party22 This variable simply cannot be calculated for the c<strong>on</strong>trol group who do not mergeor c<strong>on</strong>template a merger.143


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergerspreferences compared to voters in the largest merger partner shouldc<strong>on</strong>centrate their votes more if party preferences are an importantaspect of strategic voting. Note that since the diffparty variable isbased <strong>on</strong> the 2004 electi<strong>on</strong> outcome it is time invariant. Excludingdiffparty*after is not a problem, because it is equal to diffparty.Finally, we analyze whether the locati<strong>on</strong> of public services (schools,basic health care centers etc.) matters to voters. It is plausible toassume that there is pressure to c<strong>on</strong>centrate services to the center ofthe largest <strong>municipal</strong>ity of a merger, and thus, the farther away thecenter is the more costs voters have to bear when accessing theseservices after a merger. We try to capture these effects by calculatingfor each merged <strong>municipal</strong>ity the distance between its pre-mergercenter and the center of largest <strong>municipal</strong>ity in the merger. Using thisvariable, the DID model can be written asy = δ + δ treated + δ dist + δ after + δ treated ⋅after(4)it 0 1 i 2 i 3 it 4 i it+ δ5 treatedi ⋅ afterit ⋅ disti + uit,where dist is Euclidean distance in kilometers. We set this variable tozero for the largest <strong>municipal</strong>ities in each merger group.We also estimate the DID models separately for each party within the2004 <strong>municipal</strong> divisi<strong>on</strong>. These models should reveal whether thereare differences across parties in the way that voters c<strong>on</strong>centrate theirvotes. Moreover, we can analyze whether the preference for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>representati<strong>on</strong> is str<strong>on</strong>ger than party preference.Outcomes of interestWe use four different outcomes in our analysis. The first outcome isthe number of candidates in a <strong>municipal</strong>ity. By analyzing this variable,we illustrate that for instituti<strong>on</strong>al reas<strong>on</strong>s, the number of candidatesthat voters can choose from increases after a merger. This is becausein most cases the council size of the merged <strong>municipal</strong>ity is largerthan the individual council sizes of the <strong>municipal</strong>ities before the144


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainenmerger. The number of candidates is tied to the council size becausethe maximum number of candidates for a party is c<strong>on</strong>strained to be 1.5times the legal council size. Thus, the number of candidates a votercan choose from should be higher after a merger in most cases. 23 Inthis case, if voters vote sincerely, we should expect a wider dispersi<strong>on</strong>of votes due to an increase in potential voter-candidate matches.The sec<strong>on</strong>d outcome is the total number of votes. Given that thenumber of eligible voters remains quite stable between the twoelecti<strong>on</strong>s this variable can be seen as a rough measure of turnout.Using this outcome should give us the first impressi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the wayvoters react to a merger. If different people vote and abstain in thepre- and post-merger electi<strong>on</strong>s, we should observe a change in turnout(unless these effects cancel each other out at the level of the treatmentgroup).Our main interest lies <strong>on</strong> whether voters c<strong>on</strong>centrate their votes toparticular candidates. To this end, we use two outcomes to measurethe c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> of votes that are defined asNC = max si, i = 1,..., N and H = ∑ si,(5) ( )2where s iis the vote share of candidate i in a particular <strong>municipal</strong>ityand N is the total number of candidates in the <strong>municipal</strong>ity. The firstmeasure (C) is simply the vote share of the most popular candidate.The sec<strong>on</strong>d measure we use is the Herfindahl index (H). The larger His the more c<strong>on</strong>centrated the vote distributi<strong>on</strong> is. These measures are(roughly) invariant to other changes that occur because of the merger,such as changes in council size and number of candidates. This isimportant because c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> measures that are not invariant tothe number of candidates would capture mechanical effects that arenot due to changes in voter behavior.i=123 Naturally, the overall number of candidates decreases in most cases after a merger.145


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergers5.5 Descriptive analysisWe start our analysis with a graphical example of the phenomen<strong>on</strong> weare after. Strategic voting due to preferences for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>should show up as c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> of votes to the candidates that havea chance of making it into the new council. As an example, we lookat the merger between a small <strong>municipal</strong>ity of Sav<strong>on</strong>ranta and thecity of Sav<strong>on</strong>linna. The populati<strong>on</strong>s of these <strong>municipal</strong>ities are 1,238and 27,463, respectively. Figure 2 shows the vote distributi<strong>on</strong> inSav<strong>on</strong>ranta before (in 2004) and after the merger (in 2008) and Figure3 shows the respective distributi<strong>on</strong>s for Sav<strong>on</strong>linna. Candidates whoreceive zero votes are omitted from these histograms.The distributi<strong>on</strong>s of votes in both <strong>municipal</strong>ities look roughly similarbefore the merger. Moreover, the distributi<strong>on</strong>s of votes in Sav<strong>on</strong>linnabefore and after are very similar. However, in Sav<strong>on</strong>ranta, the votedistributi<strong>on</strong> changes dramatically after the merger. Before the merger,votes were spread out quite evenly, whereas after the merger twoclear “superstars” gather a lot of votes (note the change in the scaleof y and x-axis) and also the number of candidates receiving <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>evote increases dramatically. Similar patterns, with clear evidence ofc<strong>on</strong>centrating votes to str<strong>on</strong>g candidates in small merger partners, areobserved also in the other mergers. Importantly, the overall numberof votes in these two <strong>municipal</strong>ities did not change dramaticallybetween the two electi<strong>on</strong>s.146


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne TukiainenFigure 2 Vote distributi<strong>on</strong> in the <strong>municipal</strong>ity of Sav<strong>on</strong>ranta in2004 and 2008Density0 .02 .04 .06 .080 20 40 60 80Votes 2004 Sav<strong>on</strong>rantaDensity0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .250 50 100 150 200Votes 2008 Sav<strong>on</strong>rantaFigure 3 Vote distributi<strong>on</strong> in the <strong>municipal</strong>ity of Sav<strong>on</strong>linna in2004 and 2008Density0 .005 .01 .015 .020 100 200 300 400Votes 2004 Sav<strong>on</strong>linnaDensity0 .005 .01 .015 .020 100 200 300 400Votes 2008 Sav<strong>on</strong>linna147


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergers5.6 Ec<strong>on</strong>ometric resultsIn this secti<strong>on</strong>, we present the results from our DID analysis. First,we present results from <strong>municipal</strong>ity level analysis using differentoutcomes and specificati<strong>on</strong>s. This is followed by <strong>municipal</strong>ity-partylevel analysis. Finally, we discuss some validity checks.DID results at <strong>municipal</strong>ity levelIn Table 1, we present the DID results from the specificati<strong>on</strong> in Eq.(1). The cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al units in all the regressi<strong>on</strong>s are the 2004<strong>municipal</strong>ities. The first two columns in Table 1 report the effect ofmerging <strong>on</strong> the number of candidates who received votes and thetotal number of votes. The results tell us that <strong>on</strong> average there are 95candidates in the c<strong>on</strong>trol group <strong>municipal</strong>ities and that this averagedoes not change between the two electi<strong>on</strong>s. Furthermore, the mergerdummygets a statistically insignificant coefficient meaning thatthe <strong>municipal</strong>ities that undergo a merger are no different from thec<strong>on</strong>trol group in this respect prior to merging. The coefficient <strong>on</strong> theinteracti<strong>on</strong> merger*after reveals that, as expected, mergers increasethe number of candidates a voter can choose from <strong>on</strong> average by 71.One should bear in mind that this increase takes place when the premerger<strong>municipal</strong>ity divisi<strong>on</strong> is used. In fact, the overall number ofcandidates summed over a given merger group may, and often does,decrease after a merger. This effect is due to the council size law.Looking at the sec<strong>on</strong>d column, we notice that the average numberof votes in <strong>municipal</strong>ities is about 6000 and the average is similaracross the treatment and the c<strong>on</strong>trol groups. Turnout is also similaracross electi<strong>on</strong> years. Moreover, there is no significant resp<strong>on</strong>se inturnout to the mergers. If different people vote and abstain in the preandpost-merger electi<strong>on</strong>s, we should observe a change in turnout(unless these effects cancel each other out at the level of the treatmentgroup). Since we observe that turnout is not affected, it is unlikely thatthe possible changes in the shapes of the vote distributi<strong>on</strong>s are dueto different people voting in different electi<strong>on</strong>s. Thus, we can quitesafely interpret any distributi<strong>on</strong>al changes as evidence of roughly148


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainenthe same people voting differently after the merger than before themerger. Interestingly, this result is in c<strong>on</strong>trast with the hypothesisthat a larger jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> leads to a smaller turnout. 24 The result alsodiffers from Lassen and Serritzlew (2011) who find that after theDanish <strong>municipal</strong> <strong>reform</strong>, voters in merged <strong>municipal</strong>ities felt lesscompetent to take part in <strong>municipal</strong> politics. Of course, Lassen andSerritzlew (2011) do not directly measure turnout.Table 1Basic DID resultsNumber of Number of Maximum Herfindahlcandidates votes vote share index[1] [2] [3] [4]c<strong>on</strong>stant 95.08*** 5898*** 0.0<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>*** 0.025***[5.534] [1079] [0.001] [0.001]treated 0.457 -1033 0.001 0.003*[9.179] [1269] [0.003] [0.002]after 2.314 386.7 0.004 0.001[7.927] [1586] [0.002] [0.001]treated*after 71.34*** 54.07 0.049*** 0.022***[15.32] [1882] [0.010] [0.007]R 2 0.07 0.0009 0.15 0.08N 816 816 816 816Notes: The results are from OLS models. Heteroscedasticity robust standard errors arereported in brackets. ***, ** and * indicate statistical signifigance at 1, 5 and 10 percentlevel, respectively.Columns 3 and 4 in Table 1 present our first results c<strong>on</strong>cerning votec<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>. According to the results, in a typical c<strong>on</strong>trol group<strong>municipal</strong>ity, the most popular candidate received about 6% of votes24 On the other hand, the result can be explained within the c<strong>on</strong>text of rati<strong>on</strong>alvoting. Less seats/populati<strong>on</strong> means that pivotal probability is lower, but <strong>on</strong> the other hand,the stakes are higher in a larger <strong>municipal</strong>ity and potentially also due to the merger implyingmore policy c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s.149


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergerswhile the Herfindahl index was 0.025 <strong>on</strong> average. The treatment groupis no different from the c<strong>on</strong>trol group in the pre-merger electi<strong>on</strong>swith respect to the maximum vote share, but the Herfindahl indexis slightly higher in the treatment group. Neither measure changesover time in the c<strong>on</strong>trol group. However, a merger increases thec<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> in the vote distributi<strong>on</strong>, which can be seen from bothmeasures. This increase is large (almost doubles the baseline in bothmeasures) and highly significant.Table 2DID results with heterogeneous effectsHeterogeneity:Dependentvariable:Populati<strong>on</strong>Largest partyDistanceMaximum Herfindahl Maximum Herfindahl Maximum Herfindahlvote share index vote share index vote share index[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]c<strong>on</strong>stant 0.0<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>*** 0.025*** 0.0<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>*** 0.025*** 0.0<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>*** 0.025***[0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001]treated 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 -0.011*** -0.007**[0.003] [0.002] [0.003] [0.003] [0.003] [0.001]heterogeneity 0.00004 0.0001 0.002 0.005* 0.001*** 0.001***[0.0001] [0.00007] [0.005] [0.003] [0.0002] [0.0001]after 0.004** 0.001 0.004** 0.001 0.004** 0.001[0.002] [0.001] [0.002] [0.001] [0.002] [0.001]treated*after 0.028*** 0.015** 0.040*** 0.021** -0.005 -0.011[0.010] [0.007] [0.012] [0.006] [0.010] [0.009]treated*after 0.002*** 0.001*** 0.030 0.005 0.004*** 0.003***heterogeneity [0.0003] [0.0002] [0.020] [0.013] [0.001] [0.001]R 2 0.21 0.10 0.16 0.08 0.44 0.38N 816 816 816 816 816 816Notes: The results are from OLS models. Heterogeneity refers to populati<strong>on</strong>, largest partyand distance respectively. Heteroscedasticity robust standard errors are reported in brackets.***, ** and * indicate statistical signifigance at 1, 5 and 10 percent level, respectively.In Table 2, we allow within merger heterogeneity in the resp<strong>on</strong>se tothe merger. In columns 1 and 2, we compare <strong>municipal</strong>ities within amerger according populati<strong>on</strong> size. What we learn <strong>on</strong> top of the resultsfrom Table 1 is that the vote c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> is higher the smaller amerged <strong>municipal</strong>ity is compared to the largest <strong>municipal</strong>ity in the150


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainenmerger. This is c<strong>on</strong>sistent with strategic voting where voters fromsmaller <strong>municipal</strong>ities c<strong>on</strong>centrate their votes to particular candidatesin order to make sure they gain a representative into the new postmergercouncil.In columns 3 and 4 we report results c<strong>on</strong>cerning vote c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>and differences in political preferences between merger partners. Theresults imply that smaller <strong>municipal</strong>ities with a different largest partythan their larger partner do not c<strong>on</strong>centrate votes more than other<strong>municipal</strong>ities in the same merger. We will examine party differencesmore closely in the next subsecti<strong>on</strong>.Columns 5 and 6 of Table 2 present results c<strong>on</strong>cerning votec<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> and distance. The results indicate that the effect of amerger <strong>on</strong> vote c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> increases as the distance between theold <strong>municipal</strong>ity and the new <strong>municipal</strong>ity center increases. The effectis quantitatively large. As the distance of the smaller <strong>municipal</strong>ity tothe center of the largest <strong>municipal</strong>ity in a merger increases by 10 km,maximum vote share increases by 4 percentage points.Finally, in order to separate the effects that are due to generalpreference heterogeneity (for example c<strong>on</strong>cerning the service-taxbundle) from the effects of locati<strong>on</strong> of public services, we subject themodels (2) and (3) to a horse race by estimating the following modely = φ + φ treated + φ dist + φ popdiff + φ after + φ treated ⋅afterit 0 1 i 2 i 3 i 4 it 5 i it(6)+ φ6treatedi ⋅afterit ⋅ disti + φ7 treatedi ⋅afterit ⋅ popdiff + uit.The results from this model are reported in Table 3 and aresurprisingly clear cut. According to the results, distance seems to bethe <strong>on</strong>ly relevant measure of heterogeneity. Since the estimates formerger*after*popdiff interacti<strong>on</strong> variable change compared to thosein Table 2, omitting distance related variables was probably causingomitted variable bias in the populati<strong>on</strong> difference model. However,151


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergerssince the results for the merger*after*dist are identical to Table2, omitting popdiff did not cause omitted variable in the distancemodel. Therefore, the locati<strong>on</strong> of services is the main determinant ofpreference heterogeneity.Table 3DID results with heterogeneity in both populati<strong>on</strong> anddistanceMaximum vote share Herfindahl index[1] [2]c<strong>on</strong>stant 0.0<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>*** 0.025***[0.001] [0.001]treated -0.009*** -0.006**[0.003] [0.001]populati<strong>on</strong> difference -0.0004*** -0.0002***[0.0001] [0.00006]distance 0.001*** 0.001***[0.0002] [0.0001]after 0.004** 0.001[0.002] [0.001]treated*after -0.006 -0.010[0.009] [0.007]treated*after 0.0002 -0.0005*populati<strong>on</strong> difference [0.0006] [0.0005]treated*after 0.004*** 0.003***distance [0.001] [0.001]R 2 0.45 0.40Number of observati<strong>on</strong>s 816 816Notes: The results are from OLS models. Heteroscedasticity robust standard errors arereported in brackets. ***, ** and * indicate statistical signifigance at 1, 5 and 10 percentlevel, respectively.DID results at party levelNext we analyze whether the observed effects of mergers <strong>on</strong> votedistributi<strong>on</strong> vary across parties. The results in Tables 4 through 6 areestimated using the DID specificati<strong>on</strong> in Eq. (4) and the cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al152


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainenunits are parties in the 2004 <strong>municipal</strong>ities. 25 From the number ofobservati<strong>on</strong>s, we see that n<strong>on</strong>e of the parties had candidates in all the<strong>municipal</strong>ities and that the three largest parties are represented moreoften than the other parties. In table 4, we report results c<strong>on</strong>cerningwhether parties lose votes to other parties due to mergers. We find noevidence of this. In general, the merger has no effects <strong>on</strong> the numberof votes that parties receive. This means that voters are not willingto tradeoff their party preferences for <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>. This alsoimplies that any vote c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> by voters should be within parties.According to the results reported in Tables 5 and 6, this is indeed thecase. For the larger parties, and especially for the Centre Party, theparty level effects largely mimic what we find at the (old) <strong>municipal</strong>itylevel. However, we find no evidence of increased c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong>am<strong>on</strong>g the smaller parties. Finding the str<strong>on</strong>gest effects for the CentreParty is as expected, because the Centre Party has a str<strong>on</strong>g supportin almost all rural <strong>municipal</strong>ities, but limited support in most urbanareas. Therefore, the Centre Party has most to lose from mergers interms of political power, and thus, its voters have most to gain fromstrategic voting.25 We also estimated the model specificati<strong>on</strong>s in Eq. (1) and (2). The results weresimilar to those reported Tables 4 through 6.153


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersTable 4 Number of votes by partyCentrePartySocialDemocratsNati<strong>on</strong>alCoaliti<strong>on</strong>PartyLeftAllianceGreens ofFinlandChristianDemocratsSwedishPeople´sPartyFinns Party[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8]c<strong>on</strong>stant 1351*** 1413*** 1369*** 760.8*** 1083** 374.4*** 2536*** 164.2***[79.16] [270.4] [335.0] [138.0] [4<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>.0] [58.71] [585.7] [41.27]treated <str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>5.0** 950.4** 626.0 100.2 -236.5 213.2* -1340** -8.235[287.3] [431.7] [449.7] [231.0] [517.1] [109.4] [671.7] [49.78]distance -52.52*** -80.82*** -70.22*** -28.96*** -32.90*** -20.51*** -19.721** -3.884***[11.53] [14.54] [13.34] [8.417] [10.98] [4.398] [9.123] [1.327]after -64.16 -108.7 176.3 -10.81 72.99 -3.454 -147 362.0***[106.6] [354.3] [494.4] [197.7] [666.0] [82.35] [791.5] [119.6]treated*after -15.34 -15.68 -7.480 -80.69 -58.50 -68.83 -189.2 -56.62[398.0] [580.6] [668.6] [321.3] [742.4] [149.2] [899.1] [141.2]treated*after 0.787 8.019 -3.715 4.006 3.399 3.628 -2.234 -11.24****distance [15.50] [19.28] [19.19] [10.81] [14.07] [5.576] [13.36] [3.078]R 2 0.07 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.03 0.10 0.03Number of observati<strong>on</strong>s 786 783 768 635 425 535 138 433Notes: The results are from OLS models where the dependent variable is the total number of votes. Heteroscedasticity robuststandard errors are reported in brackets. ***, ** and * indicate statistical signifigance at 1, 5 and 10 percent level, respectively.154


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne TukiainenTable 5 Maximum vote share by partyCentrePartySocialDemocratsNati<strong>on</strong>alCoaliti<strong>on</strong>PartyLeftAllianceGreens ofFinlandChristianDemocratsSwedishPeople´sPartyFinns Party[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8]c<strong>on</strong>stant 0.050*** 0.129*** 0.121*** 0.167*** 0.173*** 0.171*** 0.047*** 0.222***[0.004] [0.011] [0.012] [0.018] [0.031] [0.022] [0.016] [0.034]treated 0.012 -0.041** -0.080*** -0.060 -0.124*** -0.068 0.007 -0.076[0.015] [0.020] [0.021] [0.037] [0.044] [0.046] [0.026] [0.071]distance 0.002* 0.004*** 0.007*** 0.009*** 0.017*** 0.011*** 0.003 0.018***[0.001] [0.001] [0.002] [0.002] [0.004] [0.004] [0.002] [0.004]after 0.010 0.016 0.022 0.011 0.047 0.089*** 0.005 0.017[0.006] [0.017] [0.017] [0.025] [0.041] [0.033] [0.023] [0.042]treated*after 0.003 -0.041 0.002 0.037 0.022 -0.028 0.279*** 0.051[0.023] [0.030] [0.031] [0.051] [0.060] [0.062] [0.093] [0.086]treated*after 0.006*** 0.007*** 0.005* 0.001 -0.008* 0.002 0.003 -0.010***distance [0.002] [0.002] [0.003] [0.003] [0.004] [0.004] [0.005] [0.005]R 2 0.26 0.11 0.12 0.08 0.09 0.11 0.40 0.08Number of observati<strong>on</strong>s 786 783 768 635 425 535 138 433Notes: The results are from OLS models where the dependent variable is maximum vote share received by <strong>on</strong>e candidate.Heteroscedasticity robust standard errors are reported in brackets. ***, ** and * indicate statistical signifigance at 1, 5 and 10percent level, respectively.155


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersTable 6 Herfindahl index by partyCentrePartySocialDemocratsNati<strong>on</strong>alCoaliti<strong>on</strong>LeftAllianceGreens ofFinlandChristianDemocratsSwedishPeople´sFinns Party[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8]c<strong>on</strong>stant 0.072*** 0.160*** 0.175*** 0.288*** 0.423*** 0.371*** 0.236*** 0.499***[0.004] [0.009] [0.010] [0.017] [0.029] [0.018] [0.048] [0.032]treated 0.011 -0.072*** -0.097*** -0.0<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>* -0.191*** -0.111*** 0.105 -0.045[0.011] [0.018] [0.025] [0.033] [0.044] [0.036] [0.116] [0.069]after 0.000 0.005*** 0.007*** 0.005** 0.018*** 0.013*** -0.006* 0.011**[0.001] [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] [0.003] [0.002] [0.003] [0.004]distance 0.003 0.023 0.012 0.002 0.013 0.067** 0.03 -0.05[0.005] [0.014] [0.016] [0.023] [0.040] [0.028] [0.072] [0.039]treated*after -0.013 -0.043* -0.018 -0.062 -0.051 -0.081* 0.040 -0.087[0.015] [0.025] [0.032] [0.042] [0.0<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>] [0.049] [0.153] [0.082]treated*after 0.006*** 0.003 0.003 0.003 -0.012*** -0.005* 0.009* -0.007*distance [0.001] [0.002] [0.003] [0.003] [0.004] [0.003] [0.005] [0.005]R 2 0.22 0.09 0.09 0.04 0.11 0.08 0.09 0.05Number of observati<strong>on</strong>s 786 783 768 635 425 535 138 433Notes: The results are from OLS models where the dependent variable is the Herfindahl index for votes. Heteroscedasticityrobust standard errors are reported in brackets. ***, ** and * indicate statistical signifigance at 1, 5 and 10 percent level,respectively.156


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne TukiainenDiscussi<strong>on</strong> and validity checksThere are several potential alternative explanati<strong>on</strong>s that couldexplain our basic DID results in Table 1. The first alternativeexplanati<strong>on</strong> is that due to a merger some prominent nati<strong>on</strong>alpoliticians or other “superstars” become available to all voters ofthe merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities. This could happen especially when asmall <strong>municipal</strong>ity mergers with a larger city. However, this does notseem to be the case in our data. For example in the Sav<strong>on</strong>ranta andSav<strong>on</strong>linna case, <strong>on</strong>e of the two superstars in Sav<strong>on</strong>ranta 2008 was a<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> incumbent and the other a new candidate. The sec<strong>on</strong>d alternativeexplanati<strong>on</strong> is gatekeeping by political parties. If the set of available<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> candidates becomes very limited after a merger, the candidatethat the voter prefers may no l<strong>on</strong>ger be available. Thus, our resultmay not imply strategic voting, but simply a change in the choiceset. Both of these stories are also c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the heterogeneouseffects results with respect to populati<strong>on</strong> difference, but it is hard toimagine why these explanati<strong>on</strong>s would show up as heterogeneity indistance. Therefore, we are c<strong>on</strong>fident that our main story of strategicvoting, preferences over <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> and the locati<strong>on</strong> ofservices are driving the results.The fact that mergers were decided endogenously by the <strong>municipal</strong>itiesis a challenge to internal validity of the results. It is plausible thatsome unobservable factors may have an effect <strong>on</strong> both merging andpost-merger vote decisi<strong>on</strong>s. However, even if this is the case, theheterogeneous effects analysis should be internally valid, becausethere the main comparis<strong>on</strong> is within mergers. Thus, these analysesshould not be biased by factors that cause the mergers. We repeatedour DID analysis using <strong>on</strong>ly the sample of <strong>municipal</strong>ities that mergedand the results remained largely the same, even though we lose a lotof degrees of freedom in doing so.Some of these c<strong>on</strong>cerns could be alleviated using placebo tests. Onepossibility would be to use <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong> data from 2000 and2004 as placebo because merging was rare between these electi<strong>on</strong>s.Unfortunately, polling district level electi<strong>on</strong> data is not availablefrom the 2000 <strong>municipal</strong> electi<strong>on</strong>s. This also means that we cannot157


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergerstest for comm<strong>on</strong> trends. Another opti<strong>on</strong> for a placebo would be to usevoting data <strong>on</strong> parliamentary electi<strong>on</strong>s. However, this is not possiblebecause the closest parliamentary electi<strong>on</strong>s were held at 2003 and2007, and in 2007 <strong>on</strong>ly some of the analyzed mergers had taken place.Furthermore, external validity of the results is an open issue. Onthe <strong>on</strong>e hand, the mergers involve a significant share of Finnish<strong>municipal</strong>ities, the effects are str<strong>on</strong>g and the within comparis<strong>on</strong>involves very heterogeneous set of coaliti<strong>on</strong>s. Therefore, <strong>on</strong>e couldargue that it is safe to generalize the results to Finland. On the otherhand, merging is a major decisi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> part of the <strong>municipal</strong>itiesand it could be, for example, that merged <strong>municipal</strong>ities are morehomogenous in terms of voter preferences than <strong>municipal</strong>ities thatchoose not to merge. Furthermore, we cannot generalize the resultsto other countries, if they have very different political instituti<strong>on</strong>sor <strong>municipal</strong>ities are resp<strong>on</strong>sible for different tasks. As usual, metaanalysisin other countries with merger activity would be useful.5.7 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>sIn this paper, we analyzed empirically whether voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>representati<strong>on</strong> and whether they vote strategically in order to obtain a<str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representative. The identifying variati<strong>on</strong> in our analysis comesfrom changes in political competiti<strong>on</strong> caused by <strong>municipal</strong> mergers.The analysis was possible due to a unique individual candidate andpolling district level data. Using these data a merged <strong>municipal</strong>ity canbe decomposed into the original pre-merger <strong>municipal</strong>ities and thismakes it possible to trace back the vote distributi<strong>on</strong>s of candidatesat the pre-merger <strong>municipal</strong> level. These data facilitate differencein-differencesanalysis where the unit of observati<strong>on</strong> is the old<strong>municipal</strong>ity and voting data come from electi<strong>on</strong>s before and afterthe merger wave.We found that voters in <strong>municipal</strong>ities that underwent a merger pooltheir votes to str<strong>on</strong>g candidates compared to voters in <strong>municipal</strong>itiesthat did not merge. Moreover, this effect is heterogeneous both in158


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne Tukiainenthe relative size of the merged <strong>municipal</strong>ities and their geographicdistance. In smaller merging <strong>municipal</strong>ities, the pooling effect ismuch larger than in the larger merging partners. The heterogeneity inthe effect is even larger with respect to distance, and when analyzingdistance jointly with populati<strong>on</strong> differences, <strong>on</strong>ly the distance matters.This implies that the locati<strong>on</strong> of services is the most important reas<strong>on</strong>why voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>. We also found that votersc<strong>on</strong>centrate votes within but not between parties. This means thatwhile <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong> is important, voters are not willing to crossparty lines in order to guarantee <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> representati<strong>on</strong>.In additi<strong>on</strong> to shedding light <strong>on</strong> the nature of preferences over <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g>representati<strong>on</strong>, our results can be seen as an important c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>to a surprisingly scarce empirical literature <strong>on</strong> strategic voting. Aninteresting future avenue for research would be to analyze whethervoters from merged <strong>municipal</strong>ities actually succeed in electing theirpreferred candidates by c<strong>on</strong>centrating votes and whether this has aneffect <strong>on</strong> subsequent policy decisi<strong>on</strong>s in the merged <strong>municipal</strong>ity.159


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersReferencesAlesina, A. – Spolaore, E. (1997): On the Number and Size of Nati<strong>on</strong>s. QuarterlyJournal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 112(4), 1027–1056.Alesina, A. – Spolaore, E. (2003): The Size of Nati<strong>on</strong>s. Cambridge: MIT Press.Alesina, A. – Baqir, R. – Hoxby, C. (2004): Political Jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s in HeterogeneousCommunities. Journal of Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 112(2), 348–396.Bayer, P. – Ferreira, F. – McMillan, R. (2007): A Unified Framework for MeasuringPreferences for Schools and Neighborhoods, Journal of PoliticalEc<strong>on</strong>omy115(4), 588–638.Bayer, P. – McMillan, R. (2012): Tiebout Sorting and Neighborhood Stratificati<strong>on</strong>,Journal of Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics forthcoming.Besley, T. – Coate, S. (1997): An Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Model of Representative Democracy,Quarterly Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 112(1), 85–114.Black, S. – Machin, S. (2011): Housing Valuati<strong>on</strong>s of School Performance, in E.A. Hanushek, S. Machin and L. Woessmann (eds.) Handbook of Ec<strong>on</strong>omics ofEducati<strong>on</strong>, Vol. 3.Boadway, R. – Tremblay, J.-F. (2012): Reassessment of the Tiebout Model, Journalof Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics forthcoming.Brasingt<strong>on</strong>, D. (2003a): Size and School District C<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong>: Do OppositesAttract? Ec<strong>on</strong>omica 70(280), 673–690.Brasingt<strong>on</strong>, D. (2003b): Snobbery, Racism, or Mutual Distaste: What Promotes andHinders Cooperati<strong>on</strong>, in Local Public-Good Provisi<strong>on</strong>? Review of Ec<strong>on</strong>omicsand Statistics 85(4), 874–883.Brueckner, J. K. (2003): Strategic Interacti<strong>on</strong> am<strong>on</strong>g Governments: An Overviewof Empirical Studies, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Regi<strong>on</strong>al Science Review 26, 175–188.Cain, B. (1978): Strategic Voting in Britain. American Journal of Political Science22(3), 639–655.Cox, G. (1997): Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordinati<strong>on</strong> in the World’sElectoral Systems, Cambridge University Press.Dahl, R. – Tufte, E. (1973): Size and Democracy, Stanford University Press.DiPasquale, D. – Glaeser, E. L. (1999): Incentives and Social Capital: AreHomeowners Better Citizens? Journal of Urban Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 45(2), 354–384.160


Tuukka Saarimaa – Janne TukiainenFischel, W. A. (2001): The Homevoter Hypothesis: How Home Values InfluenceLocal Government Taxati<strong>on</strong>, School Finance, and Land-Use Policies. HarvardUniversity Press.Fujiwara, T. (2011): A Regressi<strong>on</strong> Disc<strong>on</strong>tinuity Test of Strategic Voting andDuverger’s Law, Quarterly Journal of Political Science 6(3–4), 197–233.Gord<strong>on</strong>, N. – Knight, B. (2009): A Spatial Merger Estimator with an Applicati<strong>on</strong> toSchool District C<strong>on</strong>solidati<strong>on</strong>, Journal of Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 93(5–6), 752–765.Hilber, C. – Mayer, B. (2008): Why Do Households without Children SupportLocal Public Schools? Linking House Price Capitalizati<strong>on</strong> to School Spending,Journal of Urban Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 65(1), 74–90.Hyytinen, A. – Saarimaa, T. – Tukiainen, J. (2012): Re-electi<strong>on</strong> Incentives andPolicy Choices: Evidence from Voting <strong>on</strong> Municipal Mergers, <strong>VATT</strong> WorkingPaper 37.Karp J. – Vowles, J. – Banducci, S. – D<strong>on</strong>ovan, T. (2002): Strategic Voting, PartyActivity, and Candidate Effects: Testing Explanati<strong>on</strong>s for Split Voting in NewZealand’s New Mixed System, Electoral Studies 21(1), 1–22.Lassen, D. – Serritzlew, S. (2011): Jurisdicti<strong>on</strong> Size and Local Democracy:Evidence <strong>on</strong> Internal Efficacy from Large-scale Municipal Reform, AmericanPolitical Science Review 105(2), 238–258.Lyytikäinen, T. – Tukiainen, J. (2012): Voters are Rati<strong>on</strong>al, <strong>VATT</strong> Mimeo.Musgrave, R. (1959): The Theory of Public Finance: A Study in Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omy.New York, McGraw-Hill.Myatt, P. (2007): On the Theory of Strategic Voting, Review of Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Studies74(1), 255–281.Moisio, A. – Loikkanen, H. A. – Oulasvirta, L. (2010): Public Services at the LocalLevel – The Finnish Way, <strong>VATT</strong> Policy Reports 2, Helsinki.Oates, W. E. (1972): Fiscal Federalism, New York, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Oates, W. E. (1999): An Essay <strong>on</strong> Fiscal Federalism. Journal of Ec<strong>on</strong>omicLiterature, Vol. XXXVII, 1120–1149.Saarimaa, T. – Tukiainen, J. (2012): Politics in Coaliti<strong>on</strong> Formati<strong>on</strong> of LocalGovernments, SERC Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper 102.Tiebout, C. M. (1956): A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures, Journal of PoliticalEc<strong>on</strong>omy 64(5), 416–424.1<str<strong>on</strong>g>61</str<strong>on</strong>g>


Do voters value <str<strong>on</strong>g>local</str<strong>on</strong>g> reprentati<strong>on</strong>? Strategicvoting after <strong>municipal</strong> mergersWeese, E. (2011): Political Mergers as Coaliti<strong>on</strong> Formati<strong>on</strong>. Ec<strong>on</strong>omic GrowthCenter Working Paper No. 997, Yale University.Weingast, B. R. – Shepsle, K. A. – Johnsen, C. (1981): The Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy ofBenefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics. Journal ofPolitical Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 89(4), 642–664.162


<strong>VATT</strong> JULKAISUT / <strong>VATT</strong> PUBLICATIONS<strong>VATT</strong> JULKAISUT SARJASSA AIEMMIN ILMESTYNEET JULKAISUT41. Verotus, talouspolitiikka ja kansantalous – Taxati<strong>on</strong>, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Policy and theEc<strong>on</strong>omy. Vesa Kanniainen – Seppo Kari (toim.). Helsinki 2005.42. Suomi 10 vuotta Euroopan uni<strong>on</strong>issa – Taloudelliset vaikutukset. Jaakko Kiander –Antti Romppanen (toim.). Helsinki 2005.43. Suomi 2025 – Kestävän kasvun haasteet. Reino Hjerppe – Juha H<strong>on</strong>katukia (toim.).Helsinki 2005.44. Kasvumallin muutos ja veropolitiikan haasteet. Reino Hjerppe – Seppo Kari –Jaakko Kiander (toim.). Helsinki 2006.45. Finance and Incentives of the Health Care System. Proceedings of the 50 thAnniversary Symposium of the Yrjö Jahnss<strong>on</strong> Foundati<strong>on</strong>. Antti Suvanto – HannuVartiainen (Eds.). Helsinki 2007.46. Hyvinvointipalvelujen tuottavuus: Tuloksia opintien varrelta. Aki Kangasharju(toim.). Helsinki 2007.47. Vaikuttavaa tutkimusta – miten arviointitutkimus palvelee päätöksente<strong>on</strong> tarpeita?Seija Ilmakunnas – Teuvo Junka – Roope Uusitalo (toim.). Helsinki 2008.48. Hyvinvointipalveluja entistä tehokkaammin. Uudistusten mahdollisuuksia ja keinoja.Seija Ilmakunnas (toim.). Helsinki 2008.49. Terveyskeskusten tehokkuutta ja tuottavuutta selittävät tekijät. Juho Aalt<strong>on</strong>en –Maija-Liisa Järviö – Kalevi Luoma (toim.). Helsinki 2009.50. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Essays</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> globalizati<strong>on</strong> – Policies in trade, development, resources and climatechange. Leena Kerkelä. Helsinki 2009.51. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Essays</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Migrati<strong>on</strong>. Matti Sarvimäki. Helsinki 2009.52. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Essays</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> income inequality, poverty and the evoluti<strong>on</strong> of top income shares.Marja Riihelä. Helsinki 2009.53. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Essays</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> the efficiency of schools and student achievement. Tanja Kirjavainen.Helsinki 2009.54. Verotuksen ja sosiaaliturvan uudistaminen – miksi ja mihin suuntaan? Essi Eerola –Seppo Kari – Jaakko Pehk<strong>on</strong>en (toim.). Helsinki 2009.55. Talouden rakenteet 2009. Seija Ilmakunnas – Outi Kröger – Timo Rauhanen (toim.).Helsinki 2009.56. Local public sector in transiti<strong>on</strong>: A Nordic perspective. Antti Moisio (Ed.). Helsinki2010.57. Encouragement and discouragement. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Essays</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> taxati<strong>on</strong> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>government</str<strong>on</strong>g>expenditure. Tuomas Kos<strong>on</strong>en. Helsinki 2011.58. Three takes <strong>on</strong> sustainability. Juha H<strong>on</strong>katukia (Ed.). Helsinki 2011.59. Talouden rakenteet 2011. Aki Kangasharju – Outi Kröger – Timo Rauhanen (toim.).Helsinki 2011.60. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Essays</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> labour demand and wage formati<strong>on</strong>. Ossi Korkeamäki. Helsinki 2012.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!