19.12.2016 Views

Working Papers

n?u=RePEc:war:wpaper:2016-36&r=ene

n?u=RePEc:war:wpaper:2016-36&r=ene

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

† For lognormally distributed parameters the coefficients of the underlying normal distribution are reported.<br />

***, **, * indicate 1%, 5%, 10% significance level, respectively.<br />

Overall, the model is highly significant, and the signs of the parameters for nonmonetary<br />

attributes are generally as expected and also similar to the results found in the CE application<br />

in Germany (see Oehlmann and Meyerhoff, 2016). Regarding the labelled alternative, the sign<br />

and size of the alternative-specific constants (ASCs) indicate that respondents prefer electricity<br />

generation from solar energy compared to the FSQ. Wind power is also valued positively, but<br />

the parameter for this ASC is not statistically significant. In contrast, generating electricity from<br />

biomass is clearly valued negatively compared to the FSQ. Respondents do not want to have<br />

biomass production sites within 10 km of their place of residence.<br />

Our results further indicate that people generally want REPS to be further from their place<br />

of residence as opposed to near. This finding aligns with what many other studies concerned<br />

with the externalities have found, especially for wind power (e.g., see Knapp and Ladenburg,<br />

2015). With regard to the size of the REPS, the sign is positive but not statistically significant,<br />

suggesting that the size of the sites is not an important issue for respondents. The number of<br />

REPS, however, influences the probability of choosing an option positively. The share of the<br />

landscape protected from the renewable energy development does not, at least on average,<br />

systematically influence respondents’ choices. Finally, the probability of choosing an<br />

alternative is significantly and positively influenced by building new high-voltage transmission<br />

lines underground. In addition, relatively large and significant standard deviations, except for<br />

number of REPS, indicate the presence of substantial unobserved preference heterogeneity.<br />

Only in the case of the attribute indicating the number of renewable energy production sites do<br />

preferences among respondents seem to be homogenous.<br />

Turning to the main objectives of our analysis, we find both surcharge and rebate parameters<br />

to be negative and statistically significant. Regarding the situation of electricity bill increase,<br />

the negative sign indicates that the more expensive an alternative is, the less likely respondents<br />

are to choose it. In the situation in which people would receive a rebate when they chose an<br />

alternative, the negative sign indicates that smaller discounts also make it less likely that an<br />

alternative is chosen. Additionally, the results indicate that, on average, marginal utility of<br />

money is lower with a money gain than with a money loss.<br />

Two parameters among the four interactions consisting of the two monetary variables, one<br />

for the decreases and one for the increases, and the risk aversion and loss aversion parameters<br />

are statistically significant. Loss aversion seems to play a role when people would get a rebate,<br />

while risk aversion plays a role when people would have to pay a surcharge for a chosen<br />

alternative. Starting with loss aversion, the parameter shows that the more people indicated that<br />

they are loss averse in the lottery, the higher rebates they required before they would choose an<br />

alternative labelled with wind, solar, or biomass instead of accepting the FSQ. Thus, people<br />

who are more loss averse require more compensation before they accept externalities from<br />

renewable electricity production. Regarding the influence of the recorded risk preferences with<br />

respect to financial losses, the results suggest that people who are more risk averse are, on<br />

average, willing to pay less for an alternative on the choice tasks. People who are more<br />

concerned that an investment could lead to a loss of the invested money are, accordingly, less<br />

prone to be willing to pay for changing the way REPS are built in their area.<br />

To illustrate the differences in preferences between respondents with different levels of risk<br />

and loss aversion, we simulate the mean WTP associated with our choice attributes for<br />

respondents with different levels of and λ. Because our model allows marginal utility of<br />

money to vary depending on whether alternatives in the choice sets present a surcharge or a<br />

rebate to an electricity bill, it is also possible to calculate WTP with respect to income increase<br />

12

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!