30.01.2013 Views

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Employment</strong>: <strong>From</strong> <strong>Myths</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>Facts</strong><br />

Other externalities include information spillovers leading <strong>to</strong> underinvestment<br />

in export entrepreneurship at the extensive margin (Hausmann <strong>and</strong> Rodrik, 2003).<br />

That is, export expansion at the extensive margin reflects a “self-discovery” process<br />

whereby export entrepreneurs test the viability of new products on foreign markets.<br />

Once they succeed, imita<strong>to</strong>rs follow, creating a public-good problem. Spillovers at<br />

the extensive margin among exporters of the same country are documented using<br />

firm-level data from four African countries by Cadot et al. (2011), who find that the<br />

probability of survival of an exporter of good k <strong>to</strong> country d past the first year rises<br />

with the number of exporters of k <strong>to</strong> d from the same country. Strikingly, the number<br />

of exporters of k <strong>to</strong> d from other countries is insignificant, suggesting that the externality<br />

is essentially within-country. Interacting this network effect with various measures of<br />

dependence on finance suggests that the information spillover may go through domestic<br />

credit markets (using competi<strong>to</strong>r performance as a substitute for direct<br />

information on export risk) rather than through the direct firm-<strong>to</strong>-firm imitation<br />

effect postulated by Hausmann <strong>and</strong> Rodrik, although the implications are similar.<br />

If the case for externalities across exporters <strong>and</strong> industries seems fairly well-established<br />

both conceptually <strong>and</strong> empirically, what governments can do <strong>to</strong> leverage<br />

those externalities is less clear. Harrison <strong>and</strong> Rodriguez-Clare (2010) give a long list<br />

of studies whose gist is that industries supported by government protection in one<br />

form or another do not enjoy faster productivity growth. However, all these studies<br />

are vulnerable <strong>to</strong> the endogeneity critique of Rodrik (2007). Namely, if governments<br />

support industries <strong>to</strong> compensate for market failures, slower productivity growth in<br />

supported industries may reflect the underlying constraints rather than the effect of<br />

(endogenous) industrial policies.<br />

A few case studies identify industries successfully supported by industrial policy.<br />

For instance, Hansen, Jensen <strong>and</strong> Madsen (2003) show how Denmark’s subsidies <strong>to</strong><br />

wind power (a guaranteed-price scheme for wind power combined with an obligation<br />

<strong>to</strong> buy for power companies that was also adopted in other EU countries, <strong>and</strong> a<br />

favourable tax treatment of investments in wind-turbine manufacturing) have helped<br />

create an industry that, by the early 2000s, supplied half the world’s dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

wind turbines. As export sales were not subsidized (although they could possibly be<br />

cross-subsidized by Denmark’s four large manufacturers), their growth was suggestive<br />

of success. Hansen, Jensen <strong>and</strong> Madsen indeed show evidence of strong learning<br />

economies. They also argue that overall benefits from the industry’s development<br />

had, by the early 2000s, outweighed the <strong>to</strong>tal cost of the subsidies, although the calculation<br />

is complex.<br />

Export promotion has a more uneven record. After reviewing the mixed evidence<br />

so far, Lederman, Olarreaga <strong>and</strong> Pay<strong>to</strong>n (2006, 2009) find, on the basis of crosscountry<br />

evidence, extremely high rates of return on public money invested in<br />

export-promotion agencies (EPAs). Some conditions, however, must be fulfilled, including<br />

private-sec<strong>to</strong>r involvement in agency management. They also find strongly<br />

diminishing returns; that is, a little money does a lot of good, but a lot of money<br />

does not. A recent impact evaluation of Tunisia’s export-promotion agency by<br />

Gourdon et al. (2011) sheds some light on whether export promotion promotes<br />

276

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!