Wirtschaftsgeographie - Institut für Wirtschafts- und ...
Wirtschaftsgeographie - Institut für Wirtschafts- und ...
Wirtschaftsgeographie - Institut für Wirtschafts- und ...
Transform your PDFs into Flipbooks and boost your revenue!
Leverage SEO-optimized Flipbooks, powerful backlinks, and multimedia content to professionally showcase your products and significantly increase your reach.
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong><br />
<strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
BUCHENVERLAG<br />
Informal Dynamics<br />
in Asian Megacities<br />
56. Jahrgang, 2012, Heft 1-2
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
The German Journal of Economic Geography · 56. Jahrgang 2012 · Heft 1-2· Begründet von Dr. Irmfried Siedentop<br />
Die Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> wird in Social Sciences Citation Index (SSCI), Social Scisearch <strong>und</strong> Journal Citation<br />
Reports/Social Sciences Edition gelistet <strong>und</strong> ausgewertet. – The German Journal of Economic Geography is indexed and abstracted<br />
in Social Sciences Citation Index (SSCI), Social Scisearch and Journal Citation Reports/Social Sciences Edition.<br />
Herausgeber – Editors<br />
Prof. Dr. Walter Thomi Prof. i. R. Dr. Karl Vorlaufer<br />
<strong>Institut</strong> <strong>für</strong> Geowissenschaften Heidenfeldstr. 11<br />
Fachgruppe <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> 65812 Bad Soden am Taunus<br />
Martin-Luther-Universität Halle-Wittenberg<br />
Von-Seckendorff-Platz 4<br />
06099 Halle (Saale)<br />
Wissenschaftlicher Beirat – Advisory Board<br />
Prof. Dr. Christian Berndt, Zürich Prof. Dr. Jürgen Oßenbrügge, Hamburg<br />
Prof. i. R. Dr. Winfried Flüchter, Duisburg-Essen Prof. i. R. Dr. Eike W. Schamp, Frankfurt am Main<br />
Prof. Dr. Martina Fromhold-Eisebith, Aachen Prof. Dr. Rolf Sternberg, Hannover<br />
Prof. Dr. Johannes Glückler, Heidelberg Prof. Dr. Simone Strambach, Marburg<br />
Prof. Dr. Thomas Krings, Freiburg i. Br.<br />
Schriftleitung – Editorial Management<br />
Dr. Helmut Schneider<br />
Arbeitsgebiet Kulturgeographie (Fakultät <strong>für</strong> Gesellschaftswissenschaften) – Universität Duisburg-Essen<br />
Campus Duisburg, Lotharstr. 65, D-47048 Duisburg<br />
Tel.: 0203379 1365/1742, Fax: 02033793516, eMail: helmut.schneider@uni-due.de<br />
Internet: www.wirtschaftsgeographie.com<br />
Inhalt<br />
Editorial: Informal dynamics of economic processes – some remarks<br />
on the potential of the informality concept<br />
Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties: Organisation of firm networks in the<br />
1 – 8<br />
electronics industry in the Greater Pearl River Delta, China<br />
Frank Bickenbach, Wan-Hsin Liu; Firm characteristics and informal governance of business<br />
9 – 24<br />
operations in the Pearl River Delta, China<br />
Markus Keck, Hans-Georg Bohle, Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity. Informal relations<br />
25 – 42<br />
and risk adaptation among food wholesalers in Dhaka, Bangladesh<br />
Pamela Hartmann Kilian, Daniel Schiller, Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality and labour turnover in the<br />
43 – 57<br />
electronics industry of the Pearl River Delta, China: Contrasting employer and employee perspectives<br />
Wenying Fu, Daniel Schiller, Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity and organizational<br />
58 – 79<br />
proximity in product innovation: Empirical insight from the Pearl River Delta, China<br />
Friederike Schröder, Michael Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta:<br />
80 – 96<br />
Investigating economic restructuring in Guangzhou 97 – 112<br />
Buchbesprechungen 113 – 120<br />
Moderation: Dr. Daniel Schiller, <strong>Institut</strong> <strong>für</strong> <strong>Wirtschafts</strong>- <strong>und</strong> Kulturgeographie, Leibniz Universität Hannover, Schneiderberg<br />
50 , 30167 Hannover , eMail: schiller@wigeo.uni-hannover.de<br />
Mitarbeiterinnen <strong>und</strong> Mitarbeiter des vorliegenden Heftes: Frank Bickenbach, <strong>Institut</strong>e <strong>für</strong> Weltwirtschaft Kiel, Hindenburgufer<br />
66, 24105 Kiel, eMail: frank.bickenbach@ifw-kiel.de; Prof. Dr. Hans-Georg Bohle, Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>,<br />
Universität Bonn, Meckenheimer Allee 166, 53115 Bonn, eMail: bohle@geographie.uni-bonn.de; Prof. Dr. Revilla Diez,<br />
<strong>Institut</strong> <strong>für</strong> <strong>Wirtschafts</strong>- <strong>und</strong> Kulturgeographie, Leibniz Universität Hannover, Schneiderberg 50, 30167 Hannover, eMail:<br />
diez@wigeo.uni-hannover.de; Dr. Wenying Fu, School of Geography, South China Normal University, Zhongshan West<br />
Road No. 55, Tianhe District, Gungazhou, Peoples Republic of China, eMail: ferlicity31@163.com; Pamela Hartmann Kilian,<br />
Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>, Universität Köln, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Köln, eMail: pamela.hartmann@unikoeln.de;<br />
Markus Keck, Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>, Universität Bonn, Meckenheimer Allee 166, 53115 Bonn, eMail:<br />
markus.keck@geographie.uni-bonn.de; Prof. Dr. Frauke Kraas, Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>, Universität Köln, Albertus-Magnus-Platz,<br />
50923 Köln, eMail: f.kraas@uni-koeln.de; Wan-Hsin Liu, <strong>Institut</strong>e <strong>für</strong> Weltwirtschaft Kiel, Hindenburgufer 66,<br />
24105 Kiel, eMail: wan-hsin.liu@ifw-kiel.de; Dr. Susanne Meyer, Joanneum Research Forschungsgesellschaft mbH, Policies<br />
– Centre for Economic and Innovation Research, Sensengasse 1, 1090 Wien, Österreich, eMail: susanne. meyer@ joanneum.at;<br />
Friederike Schröder, HafenCity Universität Hamburg, Averhoffstr. 38, 22085 Hamburg, eMail: friederike.<br />
schroeder@hcu-hamburg.de; Dr. Michael Waibel, Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>, Universität Hamburg, B<strong>und</strong>esstr. 55, 20146<br />
Hamburg, eMail:waibel@geowiss.uni-hamburg.de; Wolfgang-Peter Zingel, Südasien-<strong>Institut</strong>, Abt. Internationale Wirtschaft,<br />
Universität Heidelberg, Im Neuenheimer Feld 330, 69120 Heidelberg, eMail: h93@ix.urz.uni-heidelberg.de<br />
Titelfoto: Die Entstehung neuer Megastädte in China <strong>und</strong> die informelle Dynamik des Industrialisierungs- <strong>und</strong> Urbanisierungsprozesses<br />
wird in der an Hongkong grenzenden Metropole Shenzhen besonders augenfällig. Wo heute mehr als zehn<br />
Millionen Menschen leben, befanden sich vor 30 Jahren nur vereinzelte Fischerdörfer (Foto: Daniel Schiller, August 2009).
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S.1-8<br />
Editorial<br />
Informal dynamics of economic processes<br />
Remarks on the potential of the informality concept<br />
The aim of this special issue is to expand the<br />
concept of informality by incorporating recent<br />
approaches from institutional economics and<br />
governance theory. The concept is applied empirically<br />
to analyse economic processes in the<br />
context of mega-urban regions and global<br />
change. This introduction outlines the conceptual<br />
approach by focusing on the advancements<br />
in comparison to earlier informality paradigms.<br />
It discusses the added value of a new informality<br />
perspective for economic geography and<br />
explains how the individual papers fit in. The<br />
contributions to this special issue are based on<br />
research projects that were carried out within<br />
the Priority Programme (SPP) 1233 “Megacities<br />
– Megachallenge: The Informal Dynamics<br />
of Global Change” f<strong>und</strong>ed by the German Research<br />
Fo<strong>und</strong>ation (Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft),<br />
whose support of the projects is<br />
thankfully acknowledged.<br />
The shifting conceptualisations<br />
of informality over time<br />
The terms ‘informal’ and ‘informality’ have a<br />
connotation of inferiority in the sense of ‘unofficial’<br />
or ‘without form’, but they can also be<br />
<strong>und</strong>erstood in a positive way as ‘casual’ with a<br />
focus on freedom of action. This simple illustration<br />
shows the ambivalent character of informality.<br />
The term informality was first used<br />
in the 1970s by the ILO (1972) and HART<br />
(1973) in several reports about the informal<br />
sector in developing countries. Their informal<br />
sector comprises all economic activities that<br />
are not organised in line with the legal, technological<br />
and managerial standards of modern<br />
sectors in developed countries. By drawing a<br />
clear line between the formal and the informal,<br />
these studies focused on those niches of the<br />
economy that (i) helped migrants in urban areas<br />
and slum dwellers to survive (survival<br />
economies), (ii) carried out illegal activities in<br />
the <strong>und</strong>ergro<strong>und</strong> scene without official regis-<br />
tration and unnoticed by the tax administration<br />
(shadow economies), or (iii) micro enterprises<br />
without any substantial capital stock that do<br />
not produce for the markets of the formal economy<br />
(subsistence economy) (PORTES et al.<br />
1989; CHEN/GEREFFI 1994). German-speaking<br />
human geographers used the concept of the informal<br />
sector intensively during the late 1980s<br />
and early 1990s (c.f. SCHAMP 1989, 1993; ES-<br />
CHER 1999a). A distinct structural debate<br />
emerged aro<strong>und</strong> the informalisation of labour<br />
during the post-Fordist transition. Formal wage<br />
labour became the leading form of labour organisation<br />
of Fordism and even spread to the<br />
economic periphery. From a Marxist point of<br />
view, this is not seen as a success of labour<br />
unions, but rather as being due to the benefits<br />
of formal labour for the capitalist system. At<br />
the same time, informal labour still persisted,<br />
for example in the form of domestic work, subsistence<br />
economy and production of petty<br />
goods. A renaissance of the informal economy<br />
was more recently caused by post-Fordism and<br />
also occurred in economic centres (KOMLOSY<br />
et al. 1997). While the Marxist tradition interpreted<br />
this shift as a coordinated attack on the<br />
organised labour class, other scholars of industrial<br />
organisation economics referred to the<br />
overall gains in efficiency and flexibility of a<br />
more informal organisation of economic systems<br />
and focused on the possibilities for prosperity<br />
that this new production paradigm implicated<br />
(PIORE/SABEL 1984).<br />
This earlier informality concept was problematic<br />
due to its dualistic nature that implied a<br />
clear distinction, and which turned out to be<br />
less useful in practical research. SCHAMP<br />
(1989,12) pointed out that the formal and the<br />
informal sectors were rather the extrema of a<br />
continuum. The heterogeneity of the informality<br />
definition made it virtually intangible in<br />
empirical studies, despite the fact that the<br />
coarse character (ESCHER 1999b) of the concept<br />
resulted in its ubiquitous application dur-
2 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
ing its time. Finally, the focus of research on<br />
informality and the informal sector was mainly<br />
limited to poor developing countries with an<br />
emphasis on urban areas. This hindered the integration<br />
of informality in modern growth and<br />
development theories in economic geography.<br />
The dualistic character of the criteria that defined<br />
the informal sector resulted in the lack of<br />
a so<strong>und</strong> theoretical fo<strong>und</strong>ation of informality,<br />
which became clearly apparent in comparative<br />
studies of different countries and regions. In<br />
this context, the quote ‘The informal sector is<br />
like an elephant: we may not be able to define<br />
it precisely, but we know it when we see it’ is<br />
attributed to Hernando de Soto (MEAD/MOR-<br />
RISSON 1996). Obviously, this fuzziness impedes<br />
the application of the concept for empirical<br />
research and policy recommendations and<br />
points out the necessity of a conceptual clarification.<br />
MEAD/MORRISSON (1996) declared that<br />
they would not use the term ‘informal sector’<br />
in future studies. FRIELING (1989, 74) stated<br />
that it was not possible to overcome the vague<br />
terminology of the research object ‘informal<br />
sector’, and that the term was merely <strong>und</strong>erstood<br />
as a residual that was inferior to the formal<br />
sector. The interpretation of informality as<br />
a residual category or something contrary to<br />
the rules is problematic in that it requires a definition<br />
of what is regular or normal. The formal-informal<br />
dichotomy of the informality literature<br />
in the 1980s and 1990s was based on<br />
formal laws defined by the dominant legal system<br />
in Europe and North America. Such an Eurocentric<br />
perspective overlooks the fact that<br />
the legal tradition of the Code Napoleon of<br />
1804 might be less meaningful in other parts of<br />
the world. Therefore, an informality definition<br />
that is applicable in other macro-institutional<br />
environments should be based on a generalisable<br />
concept.<br />
The recent debate surro<strong>und</strong>ing informality<br />
shifted the focus away from a dichotomous definition<br />
towards an integrative framework that<br />
is embedded within current conceptual developments<br />
in economics and social science.<br />
Based on a new <strong>und</strong>erstanding of the state and<br />
governance, the level of practice, regulatory<br />
systems and process-related elements is targeted<br />
instead of persisting with the investigation<br />
of structural elements. The concept of informality<br />
derived from this exercise avoids a<br />
strict distinction between formality and informality,<br />
and concerns itself with the interdependence<br />
of social process and structure. This al-<br />
lows an examination of informal dynamics<br />
both within a continuum (SINDZINGRE 2007)<br />
and from a multi-dimensional perspective that<br />
focuses on the informal dynamics of institutional<br />
arrangements rather than on a static informal<br />
sector. As a result, modern approaches<br />
to informality are neither predetermined as being<br />
an inferior residual category nor restricted<br />
to developing countries, but informal practices<br />
are <strong>und</strong>erstood as a governance mode in their<br />
own right that is intertwined with formal institutional<br />
arrangements. Indications of such an<br />
integrative perspective can already be fo<strong>und</strong> in<br />
critical reviews of the informal sector by<br />
CHENG/GEREFFI (1994) and FRIELING (1989).<br />
The advancement of the informality concept in<br />
economic geography is driven by the three<br />
strands of institutional approaches in economics<br />
and social science (MARTIN 2000). They<br />
have the potential to replace the older institutional<br />
tradition of the discipline that stressed<br />
the static-structural and historical-deterministic<br />
approach by Veblen (RAFIQUI 2009). <strong>Institut</strong>ional<br />
arrangements for the governance of organisations<br />
and collective goods, as introduced<br />
by COASE (1937), WILLIAMSON (1975), and OS-<br />
TROM (1990) form the starting point for a redefinition<br />
of informality and are central for the<br />
following explanations. New institutionalism<br />
with its central authors SCOTT (1987), DIMAG-<br />
GIO (2001) and Powell (POWELL/DIMAGGIO<br />
1991) provides additional elements from organisational<br />
studies. The historical <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
of institutions by NORTH (1990) adds a<br />
dynamic-evolutionary perspective on institutional<br />
change. Furthermore, concepts of vulnerability<br />
and resilience as well as the sustainable<br />
livelihood approach that dominates geographical<br />
development studies allow for the integration<br />
of an institutional informality concept<br />
within the development debate.<br />
Informality in new institutional economics<br />
and organisation science<br />
<strong>Institut</strong>ions are defined in a broad sense as a<br />
system of rules (HODGSON 2006). These rules<br />
comprise consciously created and externally<br />
enforced formal rules, for example laws, and<br />
self-enforcing, informal ones, for example traditions,<br />
norms, conventions, or customs<br />
(NORTH 1990). Additionally, New <strong>Institut</strong>ional<br />
Economics (NIE) distinguishes between rules<br />
(= institutions) and actors (= organisations or
individuals) who are interdependent. The behaviour<br />
of actors is restricted and incentivised<br />
by institutions, but actors are also involved in<br />
the creation and transformation of institutions<br />
in a co-evolutionary way. Three levels for a<br />
conceptual redefinition of informality are derived:<br />
(i) informality of the institutional environment,<br />
(ii) informality of institutional<br />
arrangements, and (iii) informality of processes<br />
within organisations. An informality concept<br />
that is informed by institutional economics<br />
is not primarily focused on the structural<br />
elements (Which transactions are carried<br />
out?), but on the <strong>und</strong>erlying practices (How<br />
are transactions carried out?) and dynamic<br />
processes (What impact does co-evolution of<br />
institutional environment and arrangements<br />
have on institutional change?).<br />
<strong>Institut</strong>ional environment: The institutional environment<br />
has an informal and a formal component<br />
which are intentionally <strong>und</strong>erstood as<br />
interdependent in a co-evolutionary relationship<br />
by NORTH (1990), not in a dualistic, mutually<br />
exclusive way. Acceptance and enforceability<br />
of new formal institutions depends on<br />
the fit with existing informal institutions. The<br />
externally imposed adoption of rules and regulations<br />
during the transition of previously<br />
planned economies into market economies is a<br />
frequently cited example (STIGLITZ 1999;<br />
ROLAND 2000). It has been shown by DE SOTO<br />
(2000) that a lack of alignment of formal rules<br />
of capitalism with informal institutions resulted<br />
in dysfunctional institutional frameworks or<br />
institutional chaos. A central question of this<br />
strand of institutional informality at the process<br />
level is whether the institutional environment<br />
is better shaped by governments or related public<br />
actors in a top-down manner, or in a self-organised<br />
bottom-up manner through unintended<br />
effects of the aggregate behaviour of individuals.<br />
OSTROM (1990) explained why one should<br />
be sceptical about leaving formation and enforcement<br />
of institutions for collective action<br />
mainly to governmental bodies, and proved it<br />
by using the example of the commons. The<br />
Austrian school of economics (HAYEK 1973)<br />
has also indicated that the aggregate order of<br />
economy and space is brought about by complex<br />
interaction of its actors. Self-organisation<br />
and emergence of the institutional environment<br />
are <strong>und</strong>erstood as an expression of informality.<br />
<strong>Institut</strong>ional arrangements: <strong>Institut</strong>ional arrangements,<br />
i.e. contracts among economic ac-<br />
Editorial 3<br />
tors in a broad sense, are the central focus of<br />
the informality perspective in NIE. GUHA-<br />
KHASNOBIS et al. (2006) distinguish between<br />
two levels which can be applied for the analysis<br />
of informality of institutional arrangements.<br />
At the first level, the interdependence of an institutional<br />
arrangement with its formal and informal<br />
institutional environment is described<br />
and the explanatory power of the institutional<br />
environment for the arrangement is exposed.<br />
At the second level, the structuration of the institutional<br />
arrangement itself is depicted in several<br />
dimensions, the formal and informal aspects<br />
of which are not necessarily mutually exclusive,<br />
but mostly complementary. In a<br />
multi-dimensional approach, LI (2007) defined<br />
five dimensions to characterise the formal and<br />
informal contents of institutional arrangements:<br />
formation (exogenous vs. endogenous),<br />
codification (explicit vs. implicit), enforcement<br />
(tight and strict vs. loose and flexible), power<br />
(hierarchical vs. horizontal) and personalisation<br />
(depersonalised vs. personalised). Informality<br />
thus possesses a subjective, emotional<br />
and personal character, while formality is objectively<br />
based on facts and cognition. It is important<br />
to mention that this should not result in<br />
new dichotomies, but rather in multiple dimensions<br />
that allow for continuous specification of<br />
institutional arrangements within the formality-informality<br />
nexus.<br />
The multidimensional, non-dichotomous character<br />
of informality is illustrated by comparing<br />
the advantages of particular institutional<br />
arrangements. In most real world situations,<br />
economic activities are embedded flexibly in a<br />
dynamic and complex institutional environment.<br />
In such a situation, informality is a<br />
strategic opportunity to complement formal<br />
arrangements proactively. In close connection<br />
to NIE, contract theory (HART/MOORE 1999,<br />
2004) has shown that most contracts are unable<br />
to comprehend completely the object that is to<br />
be regulated in a formal way due to complexity<br />
and uncertainty. Therefore, contracts remain<br />
incomplete at the time they are concluded and<br />
are specified and modified in an informal<br />
process during the contract period. This<br />
process is often socially embedded. Nevertheless,<br />
if a high level of uncertainty is connected<br />
with the institutional environment at a particular<br />
location or in a market, it might be necessary<br />
to adapt informal arrangements as a passive<br />
reaction to non-enforceable formal<br />
arrangements.
4 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
<strong>Institut</strong>ions in organisation science: Sociological<br />
institutionalism, with SCOTT (1995),<br />
DIMAGGIO/POWELL (1991), and in Germany<br />
MAYNTZ/SCHARPF (1995) being its main authors,<br />
looks at economic activity as a process<br />
that is embedded in a socio-institutional system<br />
or culture-specific social network. Informality<br />
is defined in this approach as interaction between<br />
individuals or groups which could be described,<br />
for example, as casual, trust-based and<br />
reciprocal. This normative-collectivist perspective<br />
adds to the rational choice institutionalism<br />
of NIE by explaining why trust is of critical<br />
importance in economic and social life and<br />
why cooperative arrangements are formed<br />
even in addition to the transaction cost argument.<br />
The aim is not to deduce the most costefficient<br />
institutional arrangement in order to<br />
reach an economic goal. In fact, embedded institutional<br />
arrangements are not just strategic<br />
means in an economic sense, but they also<br />
shape the preferences and identities of a society.<br />
Their impact is not necessarily in the form<br />
of increasing efficiency, but also in the provision<br />
of societal legitimacy of individual actions.<br />
The embeddedness perspective on informality<br />
becomes important if culture-specific<br />
aspects are introduced to explain why personal<br />
trust-based networks are chosen for economic<br />
transactions in situations where alternative<br />
governance forms are available and useful.<br />
This approach is of importance to <strong>und</strong>erstand<br />
the relevance of informality for interactive<br />
learning and the related processes of transforming<br />
and exchanging knowledge. There is a<br />
close link with the concept of social capital.<br />
Research on social embeddedness of economic<br />
processes has also shown that informal networks<br />
may have a negative impact (GRA-<br />
NOVETTER 1973; GRABHER 1993). The starting<br />
point of this argument is the exclusiveness that<br />
is an almost necessary outcome of stable, trustbased<br />
networks and that is responsible for the<br />
desired effects of these networks. However,<br />
this feature often results in the judgement of alternative<br />
options based on the position of the<br />
actor in the network, and is no longer fair and<br />
unbiased. A lack of transparency as well as<br />
gatekeeper functions of central actors or<br />
groups in the network can be responsible for<br />
lock-ins or cronyism in the long run.<br />
The relevance of institutional approaches for<br />
economic geography has been shown prominently<br />
by MARTIN (2000), who explained why<br />
the spatial differences of institutional environments<br />
and arrangements and their effects on<br />
the space economy are important topics for the<br />
discipline. A major argument for the spatial dimension<br />
of NIE is the fact that institutions are<br />
not equal across space, but are localised at particular<br />
points in space and are territorially<br />
bo<strong>und</strong>ed in their effects. Formal institutions<br />
created by the state are particularly restricted<br />
by administrative borders. However, informal<br />
or self-organised institutions also contain a<br />
spatial dimension, since they came into being<br />
due to specific local actor constellations, for<br />
example in agglomerations or local networks,<br />
and they only guide action within these spaces.<br />
SCOTT/STORPER (2003) have shown that agglomerations<br />
are advantageous due to their<br />
ability to reduce transaction costs. Based on the<br />
discussion above, it is expected that spatial differences<br />
of institutional environments lead to<br />
specific institutional arrangements in each region.<br />
This is of particular relevance if transactions<br />
are analysed that span spaces with different<br />
institutional frameworks. Furthermore,<br />
conceptual considerations and empirical applications<br />
of NIE in growth theory (ACEMOGLU et<br />
al. 2005) have revealed a major impact of institutions<br />
on differences in growth rates across<br />
countries and regions. And finally, the institutionalism<br />
in sociology gains its spatial dimension<br />
from the fact that social action is embedded<br />
in local contexts and that informal institutions,<br />
and thus actions, depend on their spatial<br />
and cultural context.<br />
Informality in the mega-urban<br />
economy<br />
The definition of informality that has been discussed<br />
so far is not restricted to developing<br />
countries or urban regions, as is the case with<br />
the older concept of the informal sector. However,<br />
there are arguments in favour of the fact<br />
that mega-urban regions, such as the Pearl River<br />
Delta in China or Dhaka in Bangladesh, are<br />
characterised by high levels of informality in<br />
an institutional sense. Mega-urban regions are<br />
more complex and disparate in their economic<br />
and social structures. They are closely integrated<br />
into global processes due to their economic,<br />
political and societal importance. Furthermore,<br />
rapidly growing mega-urban regions are characterised<br />
by an increasing speed and degree of<br />
institutional change. They are also highly vulnerable<br />
to economic, social and ecological<br />
shocks. ALTVATER (2005) identified the time
and space compression <strong>und</strong>er conditions of<br />
globalization and the rapid growth of megacities<br />
as major drivers of an informalisation in<br />
mega-urban regions, which is also visible in<br />
advanced market economies (SASSEN 1997).<br />
While the negative impacts of informalisation,<br />
for example in terms of the exclusion of the urban<br />
poor, prevail in the literature, the potentials<br />
of informality for development and competitiveness<br />
at the individual, firm and regional<br />
level, which were already put forward by DE<br />
SOTO (1989), are at least equally important for<br />
the institutional approach used in this special<br />
issue. ALTVATER (2005) also concedes that informality<br />
enables the realisation of a b<strong>und</strong>le of<br />
political objectives such as formation of cooperatives<br />
and micro-credit organisations, support<br />
of local and regional networking, support<br />
of cooperation with universities and other public<br />
institutions, and creation of a legal framework<br />
which contains much more than the mere<br />
distribution of property rights. Thus, informality<br />
may provide the flexibility that is necessary<br />
to adapt to rapidly changing framework conditions.<br />
By focussing particularly on urban governance,<br />
ROY (2005) has shown that the ability of<br />
public actors is insufficient to plan mega-urban<br />
regions efficiently, but that informal self-organisation<br />
of institutions by non-public actors<br />
and related informal arrangements for risk<br />
management and increased resilience play a<br />
central role. This does not imply that largescale<br />
infrastructures are not provided by the<br />
formal government, but due to the complexity<br />
of mega-urban regions and the often limited<br />
governance capability of megacities in developing<br />
countries, a complementary use of informal<br />
arrangements is expected to increase the<br />
governance efficiency.<br />
The increasing global organisation and integration<br />
of economic activities as a central part of<br />
globalisation remains a megatrend that shapes<br />
the spatial economy (SCHÄTZL 2000). This<br />
process is characterised, among other things,<br />
by the spatial disintegration of value chains,<br />
the emergence of global production networks<br />
and an increasing division of labour based on<br />
the principle of flexible specialisation (PI-<br />
ORE/SABEL 1984). At the same time, shorter<br />
product life cycles require firms to remain flexible<br />
by adapting to volatile markets that are increasingly<br />
plagued by bubble-like expansions<br />
and crisis-like downturns. The <strong>und</strong>erlying<br />
Editorial 5<br />
changes of economic systems result in a higher<br />
number of interfaces among companies,<br />
sites within multinational corporations, business<br />
services, and knowledge providers along<br />
the global value chain. The increasing complexity<br />
of interactions and flows and the necessity<br />
to span spatial, institutional and organisational<br />
distances reduces the possibility to fall<br />
back to standardised, completely formalised<br />
institutional arrangements and increases transaction<br />
costs, with informal aspects such as incremental<br />
and continuous adaptation processes<br />
during the interaction becoming more important.<br />
It is expected that traditional formalised<br />
arrangements will remain important, but that<br />
they will be complemented by informal ones in<br />
the sense of incomplete contracts. In volatile<br />
competitive environments, informality of external<br />
relations at the micro level may provide<br />
organisations with the amount of flexibility<br />
that is necessary to gain stability and competitiveness<br />
at the macro level. The strategic use of<br />
opportunity informality is suggested to increase<br />
flexibility and competitiveness and is<br />
covered by using the terms agility or agile firm<br />
organisation.<br />
In recent years, the global economy has been<br />
characterised by far-reaching changes of formal<br />
institutional environments defined by the<br />
state at different levels which may be observed<br />
in countries and regions at different stages of<br />
development. The institutional fabric of developed<br />
countries in Western Europe and North<br />
America was adapted to the requirements of a<br />
globalised economy with further ro<strong>und</strong>s of<br />
deregulation and liberalisation. Previously centrally<br />
planned economies have been involved<br />
in a f<strong>und</strong>amental transition process since the<br />
1980s which is still going on in countries that<br />
have chosen a gradual strategy, such as China.<br />
The integration of developing countries into<br />
global value chains and the rapid industrialisation<br />
of regions in East and Southeast Asia are a<br />
related result of globalising forces in the first<br />
ro<strong>und</strong>, but have also been a driver of the most<br />
recent ro<strong>und</strong> of globalisation.<br />
Amidst these changes, it is particularly relevant<br />
to analyse the fit of new formal and existing informal<br />
institutions and to assess how economic<br />
actors cope with frictions of institutional<br />
systems. Since informal institutions are transformed<br />
slower than formal ones, it is very likely<br />
that self-organised institutions and institutional<br />
arrangements will be defined by the eco-
6 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
nomic actors themselves as a substitute for<br />
missing or dysfunctional formal institutions set<br />
by the state, at least for a certain period of time<br />
during accelerated institutional change. At the<br />
same time, the transition from plan to market<br />
redefines the relationship between the state and<br />
the market as well as that among individual<br />
economic actors. Uncertainties related to this<br />
process are expected to be bridged or reduced<br />
by the emergence of hybrid institutions and<br />
arrangements. However, necessity informality<br />
induced by rapid institutional change is rather<br />
expected to be a temporary phenomenon that<br />
arises from the necessity to substitute for missing<br />
or dysfunctional formal institutions.<br />
The six papers that were accepted for publication<br />
in this special issue specify different aspects<br />
of the institutional approach to informality<br />
and provide empirical tests and illustrations.<br />
Five papers deal with the mega-urban<br />
region of the Pearl River Delta, China, and one<br />
paper with the megacity of Dhaka, Bangladesh.<br />
Susanne Meyer deals with customer-supplier<br />
relationships and provides empirical facts that<br />
support the proposition, that an increasing<br />
amount of informality occurs due to the higher<br />
level of flexibility of production processes and<br />
the transcendence of different institutional environments<br />
by global production networks.<br />
Firms from Hong Kong use informal arrangements<br />
not only to govern transactions with local<br />
producers in the Pearl River Delta, but also<br />
with customers on the global scale. In these<br />
constellations, contractual relationships are becoming<br />
less specified and specifiable by complete<br />
contracts, and are governed by framework<br />
agreements that define the scope of the<br />
relationship and the terms of reference in general.<br />
Personal contacts are a method of identifying<br />
capable suppliers and reducing uncertainties<br />
about capabilities and conflicts of<br />
interest through personalised trust and reputation.<br />
In the low-tech sector, a competitive<br />
edge over a large number of technologically similar<br />
competitors is achieved through reliability<br />
and adaptability in terms of delivery times<br />
and product quantities with sufficient quality.<br />
In the high-tech sector, personal relations may<br />
be a method of ensuring the technological<br />
competence of the supplier. In addition, contracts<br />
are more often enforced informally using<br />
mediation or arbitration and through social<br />
power rather than using slower formal litigation,<br />
which is also more detrimental to reputations<br />
due to its publicity.<br />
Frank Bickenbach and Wan-Hsin Liu extend<br />
the discussion about the extent and determinants<br />
of informality to a larger set of business<br />
functions. Their argument is based on the hypothesis<br />
that the availability of formal rulebased<br />
procedures increases in the course of the<br />
Chinese transition process and that informal<br />
personal governance decreases. However, the<br />
expected effects are, in general, rather weak<br />
and only significant for very few business<br />
functions. Similar to the findings of Meyer,<br />
Bickenbach and Liu conclude that informality<br />
is not a transitory phenomenon that disappears<br />
in the process of institutional transition. There<br />
is evidence that positive effects of informality<br />
and path-dependent persistence prevail.<br />
Markus Keck, Hans-Georg Bohle and Wolfgang-Peter<br />
Zingel examine whether social<br />
processes and informal adaptation to risks result<br />
in an increasing level of resilience. Informality<br />
is defined as trust-based personal relations<br />
and a high degree of social capital. Effects<br />
are fo<strong>und</strong> for the micro level in the form<br />
of greater flexibility and adaptability of the actors,<br />
and at the macro level in terms of increased<br />
resilience of the urban food system as<br />
a whole.<br />
The effects of informality and flexibility are also<br />
empirically tested by Pamela Hartmann,<br />
Daniel Schiller and Frauke Kraas, who focus<br />
on the impact of workplace quality on labour<br />
turnover and its long-term effects for upgrading<br />
processes. Labour relations are significantly<br />
transformed by the flexibilisation of the production<br />
organisation. On the one hand, highly<br />
qualified employees with long-term contracts<br />
among the core staff are expected to fulfil a<br />
large and varying range of functions with highly<br />
flexibilised working hours. On the other<br />
hand, less qualified peripheral staff are strongly<br />
affected by numerical volatility. Flexible<br />
firms organise their labour force based on the<br />
concept of the ‘breathing factory’ and use informal<br />
channels of employment that differ<br />
from strict formal regulations. In developing<br />
countries, informal employment is related to<br />
missing or incomplete labour contracts, low<br />
qualifications and an absence of social security<br />
entitlements. Finally, the long-term effects of<br />
highly informal labour relations for training<br />
and upgrading of the labour force are discussed.<br />
It is concluded that informality and<br />
flexibility ensure the short-term success in<br />
highly competitive markets. However, there is
strong empirical evidence to suggest that it<br />
may not provide the preconditions in terms of<br />
absorptive capacity and skills to move beyond<br />
the low-tech, labour-intensive segments of the<br />
value chain in the long run.<br />
Wenying Fu, Daniel Schiller and Javier Revilla<br />
Diez are explicitly looking at these upgrading<br />
processes at the firm level and potentials<br />
for the emergence of innovative milieus in the<br />
Pearl River Delta. The importance of informality<br />
for upgrading is measured by social<br />
proximity in comparison to more formal organisational<br />
proximity. Positive effects of social<br />
proximity are revealed for the implementation<br />
of a wide range of innovation activities<br />
and for coping with volatile demand. However,<br />
social proximity is mainly applied by domestic<br />
firms to acquire access to the latest<br />
technology and market information from foreign<br />
firms. Therefore, the impact on product<br />
innovation performance is still fairly small and<br />
the level of trust-based interactive learning between<br />
firms in the region remains low. This is<br />
substantiated by the fact that firms that rely on<br />
formalised organisational proximity are at<br />
least as successful with respect to innovation<br />
outputs. This paper links the institutional perspective<br />
with an evolutionary approach, since<br />
it is shown that endogenous potentials of the<br />
currently externally governed production system<br />
of the Pearl River Delta are still too weak<br />
to provide the basis for the emergence of an innovative<br />
milieu.<br />
The global integration of economic activities<br />
and the related institutional change has resulted<br />
in a far-reaching transition of the role of the<br />
state and its relationship with economic actors.<br />
The catchwords ‘new public management’ and<br />
‘public-private partnership’ demonstrate the<br />
increasing overlap of public and private actions<br />
that has resulted in a total withdrawal of<br />
the state or outsourcing of its activities in some<br />
areas. Complex bargaining processes among<br />
the actors involved, new participative institutional<br />
arrangements and self-organisation have<br />
thereby come into being for the definition of<br />
institutional frameworks. The increasing level<br />
of differentiation of government actions seems<br />
to result in increasingly informal arrangements<br />
between the state and private actors.<br />
Friederike Schröder and Michael Waibel position<br />
their contribution at the interface of state<br />
and economy by focusing on informality in<br />
planning processes for the restructuring of ur-<br />
Editorial 7<br />
ban spaces. Their case study of a development<br />
project in Guangzhou, the capital of the<br />
Guangdong province, shows that the local government<br />
reacts to the dynamic complexities of<br />
the multi-faceted restructuring process by applying<br />
innovative and flexible governance<br />
modes. Experimental policies and informal<br />
governance allowing for a certain degree of<br />
self-organisation are exclusively applied in<br />
spatially-bo<strong>und</strong>ed development zones. Recently,<br />
the government has made particular use of<br />
this approach in projects that aim to attract<br />
knowledge-intensive business services and a<br />
highly qualified, creative workforce.<br />
References<br />
ACEMOGLU, D./JOHNSON, S./ROBINSON, J.A. (2005): <strong>Institut</strong>ions<br />
as a f<strong>und</strong>amental cause of long-run growth.<br />
In: Aghion, P./Durlauf, S.N. (Eds.): Handbook of economic<br />
growth, vol. 1A. Amsterdam, 385-472.<br />
ALTVATER, E. (2005): Globalization and the informalization<br />
of the urban space. Aalborg. (Aalborg University,<br />
Development Research Series: Working Paper No.<br />
131).<br />
COASE, R.H. (1937): The nature of the firm. In: Economica,<br />
4, 386-405.<br />
CHENG, L./GEREFFI, G. (1994): The informal economy<br />
in East Asian development. In: International Journal of<br />
Urban and Regional Research, (18)2, 194-219.<br />
DE SOTO, H. (1989): The other path. The invisible revolution<br />
in the Third World. New York.<br />
DE SOTO, H. (2000): The mystery of capital. Why capitalism<br />
triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else.<br />
New York.<br />
DIMAGGIO, P./POWELL, W.W. (1991): The new institutionalism<br />
in organizational analysis. Chicago.<br />
DIMAGGIO, P. (Ed.) (2001): The twenty-first-century<br />
firm. Changing economic organization in international<br />
perspective. Princeton.<br />
ESCHER, A. (Moderation)(1999a): Informeller Sektor in<br />
der Dritten Welt. In: Geographische R<strong>und</strong>schau, (51)12.<br />
(Themenheft).<br />
ESCHER, A. (1999b): Der Informelle Sektor in der Dritten<br />
Welt – Plädoyer <strong>für</strong> eine kritische Sicht. In: Geographische<br />
R<strong>und</strong>schau, (51)12, 658-661.<br />
FRIELING, H.-D. von (1989): Das Konzept des Informellen<br />
Sektors. Kritik eines Entwicklungsidealismus.<br />
in: Schamp, E.W. (Hrsg.): Der Informelle Sektor.<br />
Geographische Perspektiven eines umstrittenen<br />
Konzepts. Aachen, 169-199.<br />
GRABHER, G. (1993): The weakness of strong ties. The<br />
lock-in of regional development in the Ruhr Area. In:<br />
Grabher, G. (Ed.): The embedded firm. On the socioeconomics<br />
of industrial networks. London, 255-277.
8 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
GRANOVETTER, M.S. (1973): The strength of weak ties.<br />
In: The American Journal of Sociology, (78)6, 1360-<br />
1380.<br />
GUHA-KHASNOBIS, B./KANBUR, R./OSTROM, E. (Eds.)<br />
(2006): Linking the formal and informal economy. Concepts<br />
and Policies. Oxford. (WIDER Studies in Development<br />
Economics)<br />
HART, K. (1973): Informal income opportunities and urban<br />
employment in Ghana. In: Journal of Modern<br />
African Studies, 11, 61-89.<br />
HART, O./MOORE, J. (1999): Fo<strong>und</strong>ations of incomplete<br />
contracts. In: The Review of Economic Studies, 66,<br />
115-138.<br />
HART, O./MOORE, J. (2004): Agreeing now to agree later.<br />
Contracts that rule out but do not rule. Cambridge,<br />
MA. (NBER Working Paper No. 10397).<br />
HAYEK, F. v. (1973): Law, legislation and liberty. Vol. 1:<br />
Rules and orders. London.<br />
HODGSON, G.M. (2006): What are institutions? In: Journal<br />
of Economic Issues, 40, 1-25.<br />
ILO (International Labour Organization)(1972): Employment,<br />
incomes and equality. A strategy for increasing<br />
productive employment in Kenya. Geneva.<br />
KOMLOSY, A./PARNREITER, C./STACHER, I./ZIMMERMANN,<br />
S. (Eds.) (1997): Ungeregelt <strong>und</strong> unterbezahlt. Der informelle<br />
Sektor in der Weltwirtschaft. Frankfurt am<br />
Main.<br />
LI, P.P. (2007): Social tie, social capital, and social behaviour.<br />
Toward an integrative model of informal exchange.<br />
In: Asia-Pacific Journal of Management, 24,<br />
227-246.<br />
MARTIN, R. (2000): <strong>Institut</strong>ional approaches in economic<br />
geography. In: Sheppard, E./ Barnes, T. (Eds..): A<br />
companion to economic geography. Malden, 77-94.<br />
MAYNTZ, R./SCHARPF, F.W. (1995): Der Ansatz des akteurzentrierten<br />
<strong>Institut</strong>ionalismus. In: Mayntz, R./<br />
Scharpf, F.W. (Hrsg.): Steuerung <strong>und</strong> Selbstorganisation<br />
in staatsnahen Sektoren. Frankfurt am Main/New York,<br />
39-72.<br />
MEAD, D./MORRISSON, C. (1996): The informal sector<br />
elephant. In: World Development, (24)10, 1611-1619.<br />
NORTH, D.C. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change<br />
and economic performance. Cambridge.<br />
OSTROM, E. (1990): Governing the commons. The evolution<br />
of institutions for collective action. New York.<br />
PIORE, M.J./SABEL, C. (1984): The second industrial divide.<br />
Possibilities for prosperity. New York.<br />
PORTES, A./CASTELLS, M./BENTON, L. (1989): The informal<br />
economy. Studies in advanced and less developed<br />
countries. Maryland.<br />
RAFIQUI, P.S. (2009): Evolving economic landscapes.<br />
Why new institutional economics matters for economic<br />
geography. In: Journal of Economic Geography, 9, 329-<br />
353.<br />
ROLAND, G. (2000): Transition and economics. Politics,<br />
markets and firms. Cambridge, MA.<br />
ROY, A. (2005): Urban informality. Toward an epistemology<br />
of planning. In: Journal of the American Planning<br />
Association, (71)2, 147-158.<br />
SASSEN, S. (1997): Informalization in advanced market<br />
economies. Geneva. (ILO – Issues in Development Discussion<br />
Paper 20).<br />
SCHÄTZL, L. (2000): <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>. Band 2:<br />
Empirie. Paderborn. (3. Aufl.)<br />
SCHAMP, E.W. (Hrsg.)(1989): Der Informelle Sektor.<br />
Geographische Perspektiven eines umstrittenen<br />
Konzepts. Aachen.<br />
SCHAMP, E.W. (Ed.)(1993): African small-scale industries<br />
in rural and urban environments. Challenges for<br />
development. Frankfurt am Main. (Frankfurter <strong>Wirtschafts</strong>-<br />
<strong>und</strong> Sozialgeographische Schriften 63).<br />
SCOTT, A.J./STORPER, M. (2003): Regions, globalization,<br />
and development. In: Regional Studies, (37) 6-7,<br />
579-593.<br />
SCOTT, W.R. (1995): <strong>Institut</strong>ions and organizations.<br />
Thousand Oaks.<br />
SINDZINGRE, A. (2007): The relevance of the concepts of<br />
formality and informality. A theoretical appraisal. In:<br />
Guha-Khasnobis, B./Kanbur, R./Ostrom, E. (Eds.):<br />
Linking the formal and informal economy. Concepts<br />
and policies. Oxford, 58-75.<br />
STIGLITZ, J. (1999): Whither reform. Ten years of the<br />
transition. Washington. (Paper prepared for the Annual<br />
World Bank Conference on Development Economics,<br />
Washington, D.C., April 28-30, 1999).<br />
WILLIAMSON, O.E. (1975): Markets and hierarchies –<br />
analysis and antitrust implications. A study in the economics<br />
of internal organization. New York.<br />
Daniel Schiller, Hannover
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 9-24<br />
Susanne Meyer, Wien<br />
The world’s factory and informal ties – organisation of firm networks<br />
in the electronics industry in the Greater Pearl River Delta, China<br />
Abstract: <strong>Institut</strong>ional transition in countries such as China is expected to go hand in hand with the<br />
formalisation of interactional behaviour in firm networks. Recently, however, a different string of<br />
arguments has entered the academic discussion emphasising the limited extent of the formalisation<br />
of firms’ behaviour despite the institutional transition being complete. The aim of this paper is to<br />
show conceptually and empirically that a balance of formal and informal interactions is considered<br />
optimal for firms due to economic opportunities resulting from informality. The Greater Pearl River<br />
Delta (PRD), where Hong Kong (HK) firms act as cross-border intermediates between global<br />
customers and Chinese producers, serves as an example for studying the degree of informality applied<br />
when operating in two distinct institutional settings. A survey of electronics firms in HK investigates<br />
the way in which firms organise their contacting and selecting as well as their contracting<br />
processes when approaching global customers and Chinese producers. The findings show (1)<br />
that the degree of informality is greater when interacting with producers in the PRD due to the incompleteness<br />
of the institutional setting, but (2) that when acting with global customers, the behaviour<br />
of firms is only formalised to a certain extent. Informal interaction also serves as an opportunity<br />
for firms and is strategically used in an innovative organisational and management<br />
processes.<br />
Keywords: informality, institutions, business organisation, electronics industry, Hong Kong, China<br />
Introduction<br />
The Greater Pearl River Delta is responsible to<br />
a large extent for the economic growth and<br />
prosperity of China. It has made itself irreplaceable<br />
in the global value chain as a supplier<br />
for electronics products. The electronic<br />
firms in the region account for 38 % of Chinese<br />
exports and 32 % of the gross industrial output<br />
(Guangdong Provincial Bureau of Statistics<br />
2007). The region is unique in contrast to<br />
Shanghai or Bejing due to the intense firm networks<br />
between Hong Kong (HK), an established<br />
hub for trade with formal institutions<br />
meeting international standards, and the Pearl<br />
River Delta Economic Zone (PRD), part of the<br />
Chinese province of Guangdong and the<br />
‘world’s factory’ in the middle of a transitional<br />
process. HK firms act as intermediaries between<br />
producers of electronic products in the<br />
PRD and the global customer base located in<br />
industrialised economies. HK firms manage to<br />
interact well with partners in two distinct institutional<br />
settings.<br />
Following the general discussion, HK firms are<br />
expected to apply informal, more personal<br />
modes of interactions with PRD producers to<br />
overcome the institutional weaknesses in the<br />
PRD, for example missing laws or an inadequate<br />
enforcement of existing laws. Informality<br />
in interactions is considered to be a necessity.<br />
Global customers, in contrast, are expected<br />
to be served in a more formal way. However,<br />
there are theoretical considerations which emphasise<br />
the advantage of informal interactions<br />
even though a complete institutional setting is<br />
in place, for example social safeguards, trusted<br />
advice, room for flexible actions. Therefore,<br />
this paper addresses a slightly different line of<br />
thought which considers informality in interaction<br />
as an opportunity for HK firms as well,<br />
rather than merely as a necessity. This paper<br />
aims (1) to contribute to the academic discus-
10 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
sion on informal interactions in firm networks<br />
by adding a new strand of argumentation<br />
which turns away from informality as a necessity<br />
(survival strategy in transitional economies),<br />
towards informality as an opportunity to<br />
respond flexibly to the changing economic environment,<br />
(2) to open ways to operationalise<br />
and measure informal interactions and (3) to<br />
present initial empirical evidence to confirm<br />
that HK firms use informal interactions independently<br />
from the institutional setting.<br />
A firm survey conducted in HK revealed to<br />
what extent informal interactions are applied in<br />
the contacting and selection of new partners<br />
and the design of contracts. The answers of HK<br />
firms pertaining to PRD producers and global<br />
customers were compared. It could be fo<strong>und</strong><br />
that HK firms also apply informal modes of interaction<br />
with their global customer base despite<br />
the fact that formal institutions are perfectly<br />
developed. It seems to be a good alternative<br />
in combination with formal modes of<br />
interaction. It suits the need for speed in the negotiation<br />
processes resulting from volatile<br />
market conditions and provides the flexibility<br />
required to change agreements. Considering<br />
informal interactions as a conscious and strategic<br />
method in business organisation, it can be<br />
viewed as a managerial innovation. Understanding<br />
business concepts in Asia may produce<br />
learning effects.<br />
In the first section, this paper sheds light on the<br />
two lines of argument from a conceptual point<br />
of view: informality as a necessity versus informality<br />
as an opportunity. In the second part<br />
the focus is turned to the operationalisation of<br />
informal interactions and methods with which<br />
to measure it. The third section presents an empirical<br />
study of whether informal behaviour<br />
disappears with the development of comprehensive<br />
formal institutions on a regional level,<br />
or whether informal arrangements are considered<br />
as an opportunity for doing business<br />
independently of the institutional setting.<br />
Smoothing business relations:<br />
new perspectives on informality<br />
The recent academic discussion on informal<br />
interactions in business relations has moved<br />
away from non-legalisation and informal economies<br />
towards the importance of informal institutions<br />
and, beyond that, even towards infor-<br />
mal behaviour. In order to explain informal<br />
modes of interaction between economic<br />
agents, there are two arguments on which to<br />
focus. On the one hand, informal interactions<br />
may be a consequence of inefficient formal institutions.<br />
Informal interactions are considered<br />
to be a necessity (WILLIAMSON 2000). On the<br />
other hand, informal arrangements and behaviour<br />
may simply be perceived by firms as more<br />
efficient, although these firms may act within a<br />
complete institutional setting. Informal interaction<br />
is viewed as an opportunity (ETZOLD et<br />
al. 2009; LI 2007; SINDZINGRE 2006). The<br />
study of whether informality in business interactions<br />
is driven by necessity or opportunity<br />
requires a particular investigation of a region’s<br />
institutional environment and its evolution.<br />
These factors shape the framework conditions<br />
for firms’ interactional behaviour.<br />
Informal interactions as a necessity:<br />
inefficient formal institutions<br />
Formal and informal institutions influence the<br />
behaviour of firms. Informal constraints are<br />
characterised by the customs, norms, traditions,<br />
culture and religion of a region. They are<br />
based on implicit <strong>und</strong>erstanding and are socially<br />
derived, which makes them inaccessible<br />
through written documents. Informal institutions<br />
are path-dependent and have a long, pervasive<br />
influence on the character of economic<br />
development. They are also roots for the development<br />
of formal rules. The two are interwoven<br />
(WILLIAMSON 2000, 595 ff.). Formal<br />
rules involve laws and regulations (RICHTER/<br />
FURUBOTN 1996, 3 ff.). Although there is a<br />
clear distinction between formal and informal<br />
institutions (rules) and formal and informal behaviour<br />
of firms (actions), it can generally be<br />
agreed that formal institutions shape the path<br />
for formal behaviour (e.g. a comprehensive<br />
contract law encourages formal contracts) and<br />
informal institutions guide informal behaviour<br />
(e.g. a culture of harmony avoids formal disputes<br />
between partners), even though exceptions<br />
exist.<br />
This picture loses its simplicity when turning<br />
to economies <strong>und</strong>er institutional change, such<br />
as China. There are two arguments as to why<br />
firms perceive a deviation from formal interactions<br />
as necessary. Firstly, formal institutions<br />
are not completely in place following the arguments<br />
of the New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics. In<br />
their absence, firms are expected to rely on existing<br />
informal institutions. Secondly, prob-
Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />
lems occur because of a disharmony between<br />
formal and informal institutions. In transitional<br />
economies, formal institutions are mainly<br />
transferred from Western economies and are<br />
slightly adapted to local needs. This is, in general,<br />
more cost-efficient and time-saving than<br />
developing a new system. However, formal institutions<br />
are not rooted in regionally specific<br />
informal institutions (WILLIAMSON 2000). It is<br />
essential for successful reforms to change both<br />
the formal institutions and the belief systems<br />
(NORTH 1990). Otherwise, firms, led by individuals,<br />
will not support the new economic<br />
rules of the game, since their method of doing<br />
business is shaped by informal institutions and<br />
is not compatible with the new rules (GRA-<br />
NOVETTER 1973). It is not only the existence of<br />
formal institutions, but rather the costs, the efficiency<br />
and the willingness to use them which<br />
makes them attractive for firms. This explains<br />
why the economic system in some nations still<br />
does not work effectively, even though formal<br />
institutions are well developed.<br />
Although laws in China have been reformed,<br />
their functionality is still limited. At the same<br />
time, the Chinese are equipped with a set of<br />
strong informal institutions guiding social and<br />
economic interactions – guanxi. Basically,<br />
guanxi describes a personal connection between<br />
two people or a network of contacts, the<br />
idea of which is to draw on established connections<br />
in order to secure favours in personal<br />
interests (DUNNING/KIM 2007, LUO/CHEN<br />
1997, PARK/LUO 2001). These informal rules<br />
are already in place and may act perfectly as<br />
substitutes for dysfunctional and costly formal<br />
rules. The traits of guanxi are manifold (Tab.<br />
1). Firstly, guanxi operates on the level of individuals<br />
and corresponds to a highly personal<br />
relationship. Secondly, guanxi is reciprocal in<br />
the exchange of favours. Reciprocal processes<br />
are seen as a supplement to formal procedural<br />
rules. They involve mutual expectations on the<br />
part of the economic agents that a favour granted<br />
now will be repaid later. It is perpetual. Reciprocity<br />
can also result in mutual dependency.<br />
Thirdly, guanxi is an intangible asset. People in<br />
the network are committed to each other<br />
through an informal and unwritten code of<br />
trust. This guards against opportunistic behaviour,<br />
as the reputations of individuals are damaged<br />
when they disappoint their partners.<br />
Fourthly, guanxi is long-term oriented. Every<br />
guanxi relationship expands the stock of relational<br />
capital. It takes time to establish a functional<br />
guanxi network. Investments are initially<br />
high, but if a guanxi network is established,<br />
it enables firms to react quickly to changes and<br />
provides them with a certain degree of flexibility.<br />
Fifthly, guanxi is transferable. If A has<br />
guanxi with B, and B is a friend of C, then B<br />
can introduce and recommend A to C. Finally,<br />
guanxi is a utility concept. It is based on the exchange<br />
of favours, not on sentiments. If guanxi<br />
with other parties is no longer achieving objectives,<br />
it is easily broken (DUNNING/KIM 2007,<br />
330 f.; LUO/CHEN 1997; PARK/LUO 2001, 457).<br />
A manager's guanxi network is part of the Chinese<br />
way of doing business. Guanxi relations<br />
as fo<strong>und</strong> in Chinese society cannot easily be<br />
created – they are socially derived and are regionally<br />
embedded. Most of the contacts are<br />
built with people in spatial proximity, as trust<br />
and frequent interaction are the f<strong>und</strong>amental<br />
axes of guanxi. The network of guanxi is connected<br />
to a certain region, although guanxi also<br />
has the potential for long-distance relations,<br />
for example when family members or classmates<br />
move. The strong definition of informal<br />
rules supports entrepreneurs in adequately<br />
safeguarding their transactions in the absence<br />
of economic laws. For example, firms are hard-<br />
Tab. 1: The traits of guanxi<br />
Traits Description<br />
Personal Guanxi is established between individuals<br />
Reciprocal An individual’s reputation is tied up with reciprocal obligation<br />
Intangible Guanxi maintained by an unspoken commitment<br />
Long-term Guanxi is reinforced through long-term cultivation<br />
Transferable Guanxi is transferable through a third party as a referral<br />
Utilitarian Guanxi is purposefully driven by personal interests<br />
Source: according to DUNNING/KIM 2007, 331<br />
11
12 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
ly able to enforce contracts in the case of conflicts<br />
due to a lack of functionality of the Chinese<br />
court system.<br />
Despite all the positive effects of guanxi, it can<br />
also lead to lock-in effects, for example when<br />
firms are forced to select customers and producers<br />
via social ties (e.g. family members) instead<br />
of choosing the highest quality partner on<br />
a market basis. In other cases, firms cannot enforce<br />
contracts without considering the fact<br />
that this could burden the relationship. Therefore,<br />
it may be expected that against the backgro<strong>und</strong><br />
of profit maximisation, the guanxi network<br />
might become more functionally driven<br />
by personal connections and profit orientation.<br />
Business connections would then be associated<br />
with moderate informality, whereas private<br />
contacts are associated with a high degree of<br />
informality.<br />
According to the New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics,<br />
institutional change in transitional economies –<br />
setting up a complete set of formal institutions<br />
in harmony with existing informal rules – is<br />
expected to lead to a gradual formalisation of<br />
interactions. However, this paper goes beyond<br />
that and follows the idea that a sophisticated<br />
set of informal interactions could still work efficiently<br />
in business operations even though<br />
formal institutions are modernised. There<br />
might be a trade-off point where formal interactions<br />
substitute for informal behaviour of<br />
firms, indicating optimal behaviour. Following<br />
these lines of thought, this paper addresses<br />
YEUNG/LIN'S (2003) call for a context-specific<br />
theorising of the economic geographies of<br />
Asia.<br />
Informal interactions as opportunity –<br />
benefiting by smoothing business relations<br />
If interactions are formalised only to some extent<br />
in the course of institutional transition and<br />
keep a certain level of informality due to more<br />
efficient outcomes, informal interactions in<br />
business are no longer transitional, but become<br />
permanent. This line of argumentation states<br />
that there is not necessarily a complete formalisation<br />
of interaction, even if sufficient safeguards<br />
are provided by the current law system.<br />
Formal and informal interactions no longer<br />
serve as substitutes, but as complements. It is<br />
considered to be an opportunity rather than a<br />
necessity. Psychological research has shown<br />
that in personal contacts, face-to-face visual<br />
clues, such as facial expression, gesture and<br />
posture, play a significant role in <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
and trusting the other party and can give all<br />
participants the impression that the others can<br />
be influenced more, thus making it appear<br />
more worthwhile to enter into cooperation<br />
(PUTNAM1993; MISZTAL 2000). MISZTAL (2000)<br />
proved that informal meetings still matter, as<br />
face-to-face contacts have the potential to draw<br />
individuals deeper into relationships with one<br />
another and to develop trust and intimacy.<br />
MACAULAY (1963) observed that business people<br />
trust in and rely on a person's word in a<br />
brief letter or a handshake, even if they take<br />
greater risks concerning the transaction. Moreover,<br />
experiments revealed that in face-to-face<br />
discussion, participants reach agreement sooner<br />
than in any other negotiation setting. This<br />
leads to greater confidence in the negotiation<br />
processes. Informal interaction contributes to<br />
greater flexibility. Firms have more freedom to<br />
adjust to specific circumstances. For example,<br />
firms can respond quickly without taking into<br />
account and discussing fixed contractual<br />
arrangements first. Additionally, studies discovered<br />
that personal contacts make negotiations<br />
more an issue between two people than<br />
one between two firms, and negotiations are<br />
less formalised.<br />
Researchers such as DUYSTERS et al. (1999),<br />
and recently PIDDUCK (2006, 265), argue that<br />
“a new perspective on partnership is needed to<br />
handle recent rapid economic and technological<br />
developments, and propose a more personal<br />
approach to partnership”. GRANOVETTER<br />
(1985) is thought to be the first to have intensively<br />
studied the effect of social networks on<br />
business success. Social networks transform<br />
into business networks and determine the<br />
choice of economic trading partners and how<br />
to interact with them. Empirical information on<br />
social networks proved the positive effects on<br />
economic development and democracy (PUT-<br />
NAM 1993; PUTNAM 2000), economic exchange<br />
(COLEMAN 1990; BURT 1992), education<br />
(COLEMAN 1988) and career success (BAKER<br />
2000). The advantages of informality have<br />
been recognised by firms. Therefore, some elements,<br />
for example face-to-face negotiation,<br />
are part of general business practices, rather<br />
than merely a specific phenomenon observed<br />
in China or HK, which may only occur there<br />
more frequently. Social networks are particularly<br />
beneficial when economic transactions<br />
take place in an environment of high risk and<br />
uncertainty. In the case of China, it must be in-
Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />
vestigated as to whether guanxi, originating as<br />
a social network, can transform into a comprehensive<br />
business network while preserving its<br />
efficient informal elements.<br />
Geography matters – regional institutions<br />
in the study region Greater Pearl River Delta<br />
Recently, the academic discussion in economic<br />
geography has stressed the spatial scale of institutions<br />
by applying concepts from the New<br />
<strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics to an institutional economic<br />
geography (GERTLER 2010; BOSCHMA/<br />
FRENKEN 2009; BOSCHMA/FRENKEN 2006).<br />
Economic interaction is shaped by a set of rules<br />
that are actively produced and reproduced over<br />
time and are typically bo<strong>und</strong> to a particular region<br />
(GERTLER 2010). Some regions provide<br />
comprehensive formal rules and laws to protect<br />
economic transactions, while others provide<br />
socially derived, well accepted informal rules<br />
of doing business. The dependency of firms’<br />
behaviour on the regionally specific institutional<br />
environment may be studied by examining<br />
cross border business operations between<br />
regions with two different institutional settings.<br />
The Greater Perl River Delta (GPRD) serves as<br />
a perfect study region for this phenomenon.<br />
The GPRD consists, on the one hand, of HK, a<br />
former British colony with a formal institutional<br />
environment corresponding to the international<br />
standard. On the other hand, there is the<br />
PRD, a transitional economy. Although firms<br />
in HK and the PRD act in distinct formal institutional<br />
settings, they have the same social<br />
roots resulting in similar informal institutions<br />
across the border. Production is usually organised<br />
in the PRD, whereas firms in HK serve as<br />
intermediaries for exporting and importing<br />
products to and from industrialised countries.<br />
HK firms are somewhat janus-faced (MEYER et<br />
al. 2009). One face is turned to the PRD producers,<br />
the other face is turned to the world’s<br />
leading firms as customers of products made in<br />
China.<br />
The unique institutional environment in the<br />
GPRD lends itself to the empirical testing of<br />
three hypotheses:<br />
(1) Firms in HK, working in two distinct institutional<br />
settings, organise business operations<br />
differently when dealing with PRD<br />
producers and global customers. According<br />
to this hypothesis, HK firms should work<br />
on a more informal basis with PRD producers<br />
due to the <strong>und</strong>erdevelopment of<br />
13<br />
comprehensive formal institutions in China,<br />
but on a more formal basis with global<br />
customers. The persistently unsatisfactory<br />
enforcement of formal laws combined with<br />
the lack of interwovenness of formal and<br />
informal institutions in the PRD lead to the<br />
expectation that Chinese firms do not yet<br />
rely on formal safeguards to ensure transactional<br />
success. FEARON/LAITIN (1996,<br />
730) fo<strong>und</strong> that social networks are better<br />
developed and interactions are more frequent<br />
within ethnic groups because they<br />
share certain similarities. Since entrepreneurs<br />
in HK and the PRD have the same<br />
ethnic and therefore social roots, their way<br />
of doing business on an informal basis is<br />
easier to realise, as it is driven by the concept<br />
of guanxi. The degree of informality in<br />
interactions is expected to be higher in HK<br />
firms’ relations to PRD firms than to global<br />
customers.<br />
(2) Since the rules of law in China have improved<br />
recently, the organisational behaviour<br />
has formalised to a certain extent, but<br />
informal organisation still prevails. According<br />
to the second hypothesis, interactions of<br />
HK firms with local producers are not completely<br />
informalised either. With the improvement<br />
of the institutional setting in<br />
China, HK entrepreneurs have formalised<br />
their relations with PRD producers to a certain<br />
extent. But since they know about the<br />
advantage of informal interactions (e.g.<br />
reciprocity, mutual <strong>und</strong>erstanding, flexibility),<br />
they may consider a combination of<br />
formal and informal interactions to be most<br />
beneficial for their relations with producers.<br />
This would provide evidence for the<br />
importance of personal interactions even<br />
going beyond the institutional setting. In<br />
the empirical section, the intensification of<br />
formal vs. informal interactions will be<br />
studied, comparing the behaviour of HK<br />
entrepreneurs when working with PRD<br />
producers and Western customers.<br />
(3) Informal methods enable HK firms to engage<br />
in more flexible behaviour and respond<br />
quickly to market and customer requirements.<br />
Informality as an opportunity<br />
implies that firms benefit from informal behaviour.<br />
One expected benefit is more flexible<br />
behaviour leading to quick reaction opportunities,<br />
for example. Trust-based relations<br />
could relax negotiation processes,
14 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
ease the changing of agreements or encourage<br />
the enforcement of agreements through<br />
social power.<br />
Operationalisation of informal<br />
interactions in business<br />
LI (2007) discussed the contrasting terms of<br />
formality and informality of firms' behaviour.<br />
He distinguished between formal and informal<br />
attributes of interaction, whereby these mark<br />
the extreme points of a continuum. According<br />
to LI (2007, 229), informality in interactions on<br />
the micro-level “refers to the nature of social<br />
ties and events as implicitly assumed, endogenously<br />
embraced and flexibly enforced by horizontal<br />
… pressures in a particularistic personalized<br />
process …, while formality as explicitly<br />
prescribed, exogenously imposed and rigidly<br />
enforced by vertical authority powers in a …<br />
depersonalized process.” To study formal and<br />
informal behaviour, he proposed dimensions of<br />
informality as a framework to study and measure<br />
empirically formal and informal practices<br />
in business interactions. He recommended taking<br />
into account the degree of personalisation<br />
in business interactions, the form of agreements<br />
concluded, the precision of arrangements,<br />
the enforcement mechanisms of contracts<br />
and the power of institutions used (Tab.<br />
2).<br />
LI (2007) divided each dimension into a variety<br />
of actions ranging from formal to informal.<br />
Taking the first dimension, personalisation, into<br />
account, he refers to business contacts that<br />
can be highly impersonal (formal) or very personal<br />
(informal). Personal processes are based<br />
on face-to-face contacts, trust between partners<br />
Tab. 2: Formal-informal dimensions in business interactions<br />
and private involvement. This may also determine<br />
the second dimension, the form of agreements.<br />
Contracts can be highly formalised in a<br />
written way or informally agreed on in a verbal<br />
way, when partners trust each other's word. Not<br />
only the form of agreements, but also the precision<br />
of agreements (third dimension) can<br />
range from very precise (formal) to openended<br />
(informal). Business culture can rely on<br />
open-ended agreements with permanent renegotiations<br />
rather than specifying details in advance.<br />
Formal and informal agreements rely on<br />
different enforcement mechanisms, which can<br />
either be very tight at the one extreme or very<br />
loose at the other. In the case of conflicts, the<br />
power used to enforce agreements can be legal<br />
via courts or social power relying on shared<br />
norms within a culture (LI 2007; SINDZINGRE<br />
2006). A firm may be characterised as acting<br />
on informal constraints in terms of customerproducer<br />
relations when dimensions tend to be<br />
specified by informal practices. In contrast, a<br />
firm is characterised as acting on formal constraints<br />
in terms of customer-producer relations<br />
when dimensions tend to have a formal shape.<br />
Here a special focus is placed on these three dimensions,<br />
namely personalisation in business<br />
interactions, the form of agreements concluded<br />
and the precision of arrangements. Along these<br />
dimensions, it will be tested empirically as to<br />
how high the degree of informality applied in<br />
business interactions is, comparing firms acting<br />
in two different institutional settings. To<br />
test the dimension of personalisation, the instruments<br />
of HK entrepreneurs for contacting<br />
and selecting customers and producers were<br />
studied. Contacting and selecting processes<br />
can be based on personal or impersonal ties,<br />
which refer to informal or formal modes re-<br />
Dimensions Formal Informal Operationlisation<br />
Personalisation impersonal personal Contacting and selecting of customers<br />
and producers<br />
Form of agreements written verbal Form of manufacturing agreements<br />
Preciseness of agreements precise open-ended Details fixed in manufacturing agree<br />
ments<br />
Enforcement of agreements tight loose<br />
Power legal (vertical) social (horizontal)<br />
Source: own composition according to LI 2007, 229ff.)
Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />
spectively. There are two arguments as to why<br />
informal means might be used in contacting<br />
and selecting processes:<br />
– In the neoclassical theory, firms are expected<br />
to contact and select their business partners<br />
by evaluating their rational factors of<br />
success (e.g. for example firm performance,<br />
product quality) (ANGELES/NATH 2000; HITT<br />
et al. 2000; SAFFU/MAMMAN 2000). This<br />
could be interpreted as an impersonal and<br />
therefore formal method of contacting customers<br />
and producers. But bo<strong>und</strong>ed rationality<br />
limits the scope of firms for assessing a<br />
potential partner's quality and reliability in<br />
advance. Even though firms can assess potential<br />
partners’ quality and reliability within<br />
a screening scheme of their own (formal),<br />
they can trust in a network of firms with<br />
pooled experiences (informal). Empirically,<br />
MENARD (2004, 361) could prove that the<br />
use of informal modes through networking<br />
to gain new customers and producers opens<br />
up additional opportunities for firms without<br />
weakening any formal modes.<br />
– Under volatile industry and market conditions<br />
with changing demand, time is essential<br />
for a firm's competitiveness. As a personal<br />
network is always ready to use, it<br />
seems to be a quicker way of activating new<br />
customers and producers at short notice<br />
(MILLINGTON et al. 2006).<br />
In order to study the dimensions of precision<br />
and form of contracts, HK firms' contracts<br />
with customers and producers pertaining to the<br />
manufacturing of electronics products were investigated.<br />
Emphasis was placed on the details<br />
fixed and the form of contracts. Again, there<br />
are three arguments as to why informal means<br />
might be used.<br />
– When the formal institutional environment<br />
does not provide safeguards for the enforcement<br />
of contracts, the incentive of firms to<br />
design precisely written contracts is low.<br />
Firms have to protect their transactional interests<br />
in other ways. A trust-based relationship,<br />
as which guanxi may be characterised,<br />
in which parties rely on reputation and reciprocity,<br />
provides informal safeguards which<br />
lead to self-enforcing contracts (POWELL<br />
1990; DIMAGGIO/LOUCH 1998; MENARD<br />
2004, 362). Despite improvements in the<br />
PRD, the institutional framework does not<br />
15<br />
provide firms with the appropriate safeguards<br />
for protecting their transactions efficiently.<br />
Even if contractual details are formally<br />
fixed and verifiable, it is still difficult<br />
to enforce them through courts (MENARD<br />
2004, 360).<br />
– Informal modes in contracting can also be<br />
expected due to the low impact of contracts<br />
in Chinese business culture. Contracts are not<br />
the results of intensive negotiations, but are<br />
seen rather as the beginning of a relationship<br />
over a much longer time period (see guanxi).<br />
Therefore, the permanent renegotiation of<br />
contracts is a process which accompanies the<br />
development of the relationship.<br />
– There is, however, another argument: Firms<br />
still weigh the costs of anticipating, devising<br />
optimal responses to and drafting provisions<br />
for future events against the value which<br />
would be lost in the case of conflicts. Only<br />
when transaction-specific investments are<br />
high is it worth incurring the considerable<br />
costs of administering complex and highly<br />
detailed contractual arrangements (model in<br />
HART/MOORE 2004, 5 ff.; MASTEN 2000). Under<br />
certain circumstances, firms are expected<br />
to attempt to agree only on the most necessary<br />
details (SEGAL 1999, 74). Besides cost<br />
motives, this is associated with greater flexibility.<br />
Firms can speed up the contractual<br />
process and revise and renegotiate on a<br />
steady platform in order to adapt to changing<br />
demand. In industries with rapidly shifting<br />
technologies and markets, firms need adjustable<br />
contracts embedded in networks to<br />
ensure the ability to react to the changing demand<br />
profiles of end customers (ERNST 2004,<br />
106).<br />
Despite the positive effects of informality on<br />
business interactions, one has to consider that it<br />
takes a lot of time and effort to build social ties.<br />
HUMPHREY/ASHFORTH (2000) showed that interpersonal<br />
relationships can also lead customers<br />
to award contracts to producers who<br />
have higher unit costs, lower quality and slower<br />
delivery times. Nevertheless, networks may<br />
also lead to a lock-in, if firms rely on them exclusively.<br />
Therefore, they need to be supported<br />
by formal structures to guard against the negative<br />
effects of informality, such as opportunistic<br />
behaviour and its intransparency (MISZTAL<br />
2000, 7).
16 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Data and methods<br />
Informality will be studied empirically, involving<br />
a comparison between the organisation of<br />
customer and producer relations of HK firms.<br />
Emphasis is placed on the contacting and selecting<br />
procedures and the contractual arrangements.<br />
To avoid sector-related skewness, the<br />
study was concentrated on one industry. The<br />
electronics industry in the GPRD was selected<br />
because of its large contribution to the economic<br />
growth in the GPRD and its dynamics<br />
(CANFEI et al. 2008). The electronics industry<br />
in the PRD is responsible for 38 % of all Chinese<br />
electronics exports and 32 % of the gross<br />
industrial output. 47 % of foreign direct investments<br />
come from HK (Guangdong Provincial<br />
Bureau of Statistics 2006).<br />
As there is a shortage of secondary data on<br />
this issue, a firm survey was conducted in HK<br />
focussing on the electronics industry. On a<br />
micro-level, a survey of small and mediumsized<br />
electronic firms was conducted in HK in<br />
2007 and 2008 to collect information on how<br />
HK firms organise relations to their PRD producers<br />
as well as to their global customer<br />
base. This was intended to show whether informal<br />
interactions are only applied in relations to<br />
PRD firms as a necessity for manoeuvring<br />
aro<strong>und</strong> institutional incompleteness, or whether<br />
HK firms also see advantages in organising<br />
business with customers in an informal way.<br />
The survey was based on the firm directory of<br />
the Hong Kong Trade Development Council.<br />
From 4,903 registered small and medium-sized<br />
HK electronic firms, a random sample of 2,000<br />
was selected. In a stepwise process, 1,000<br />
firms were chosen first, followed by another<br />
sample of 1,000 firms due to the low return rate<br />
from the first sample. The survey concentrated<br />
on firms with not more than 100 employees in<br />
HK according to HK statistical standards. Although<br />
a standardised survey was conducted,<br />
the information was collected personally in an<br />
hour-long interview to ensure high quality.<br />
CEOs or senior managers of 104 firms agreed<br />
to an interview (5 % return rate). Although the<br />
Social Science Research Center of the Hong<br />
Kong University (SSRC), who provided strong<br />
support in contacting and interviewing firms, is<br />
very professional and experienced, gaining HK<br />
CEOs for an interview proved to be very difficult.<br />
The low response rate may be explained<br />
by the fact that people in these positions were<br />
requested to participate due to the strategic ori-<br />
entation of the survey. Unfortunately, potential<br />
respondents often spend most of their time in<br />
their Chinese factory and were hardly available<br />
in HK. Moreover, we wanted CEOs to be<br />
interviewed personally in order to ensure the<br />
quality of the survey results, rather than using<br />
self-completed questionnaires, which also<br />
dropped the return rate. Additionally, HK firms<br />
are the target group of many surveys. As we<br />
cooperated with SSRC, we already had a<br />
strong academic partner for the interviews,<br />
which led to a reasonable response rate for HK<br />
circumstances, but in comparison to other surveys,<br />
the response rate is lower. However,<br />
since the collection of empirical data on informality<br />
in interactions is still at an explorative<br />
stage, no attempt was made to produce representative<br />
results. The accessibility of firms and<br />
reliability of data was of primary importance.<br />
Nevertheless, it could be proven that there is<br />
no significant difference between sample and<br />
population according to employment size.<br />
Applying informal interactions:<br />
contacting, selecting and contracting<br />
The previous sections raised the question of<br />
whether the institutional environment requires<br />
informal actions as a necessity or whether informal<br />
interactions could also be seen as an opportunity<br />
for firms. This section empirically<br />
studies the degree of informality applied in the<br />
customer-producer relations of HK firms in<br />
terms of contacting and selecting procedures<br />
and contractual arrangements, depending on<br />
the institutional environment.<br />
Contacting and selecting of customers<br />
and producers<br />
Contacting: When firms wish to contact new<br />
customers and producers, they may choose<br />
from a variety of methods ranging from very<br />
impersonal to very personal. The importance of<br />
seven different contact channels of HK firms<br />
for gaining new global customers (non-Chinese)<br />
is shown in Tab. 3. In the second part, the<br />
selecting processes of PRD producers will be<br />
studied as a comparison. Contact channels<br />
range from being very personal, and therefore<br />
informal (private contacts), to very impersonal,<br />
and therefore formal (bidding competition).<br />
HK firms were asked to assess their importance<br />
on a Likert scale (1 = very important to 5<br />
= not important). Recommendations by business<br />
partners are, as is shown in Tab. 3, the
Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />
most important (61 %). This requires a network<br />
of trustworthy business partners to receive recommendations.<br />
Whereas business contacts<br />
seem to be of importance, private networks are<br />
not (8 %). Sales agents are the second most important<br />
(54 %). Sales agents are responsible for<br />
contacting and keeping in touch with customers.<br />
The personal contact is important, as<br />
this creates an atmosphere of trust. However,<br />
sales agents account for moderate informality.<br />
In contrast, gaining customers at exhibitions is<br />
less personal, while gaining them on the internet<br />
or through bidding competitions is even<br />
more impersonal, and therefore very formal.<br />
Exhibitions and internet contact is third in<br />
terms of importance. Formal bidding processes,<br />
the contacting of former customers and private<br />
contacts are of minor importance. The<br />
Chi²-test shows that the indicated shares significantly<br />
differ from an equal distribution.<br />
Contacting channels with a medium degree of<br />
informality scored highest when HK firms contact<br />
global customers, although the institutional<br />
environment would allow them to rely on formal<br />
means only. Apparently, a certain degree of<br />
informality is conducive to business success.<br />
When firms can revert to networks, they enlarge<br />
their pool of choices for contacting and<br />
selecting partners. Very impersonal contact<br />
channels are at everybody's disposal, but personal<br />
channels are not available to all firms.<br />
Although formal safeguards can be ensured by<br />
a functional legal system in HK and transac-<br />
17<br />
tions with strangers can be ensured by contracts,<br />
recruitment within networks might still<br />
be appealing because of cost-reducing and<br />
time-saving aspects. Even if HK firms contact<br />
global customers, they prefer the use of networks<br />
and other moderately informal means.<br />
This raises the question of how guanxi networks<br />
are affected by institutional change.<br />
XIN/PEARCE (1996) and NEE (1992) see guanxi<br />
as a substitute for the deficiencies of formal institutional<br />
artifacts and failures in the legal system.<br />
Proponents of this thesis argue that guanxi<br />
will become less important in the future. On<br />
the other hand, other experts argue that guanxi<br />
is also transforming into a more functional<br />
business network. Whereas the traditional<br />
guanxi network consists of family (zijiaren)<br />
and fellows/helpers (shouren), it has now<br />
changed to strangers/business partners (shengren),<br />
which makes it more effective for business<br />
(MILLINGTON et al. 2006). Studies of business<br />
culture in HK or Taiwan are widely used<br />
to provide examples of the transition – but nevertheless<br />
survival – of guanxi in the modern<br />
market (FAN 2002; ZHANG/ZHANG 2006).<br />
The importance of business networks in comparison<br />
to private networks confirms the<br />
change of the nature of guanxi from a private<br />
to a functional network. This functional guanxi<br />
network is driven by personal connections.<br />
When firms in HK use their guanxi networks,<br />
they profit from the intangible, transferable and<br />
reciprocal character of the network. Other network<br />
members are committed either to provid-<br />
Tab. 3: Importance of formal and informal contacting channels of HK firms to global customers<br />
(in %)<br />
customers abroad (n=93)<br />
important moderate<br />
important<br />
not<br />
important<br />
Chi² significance<br />
(1) Bidding competition 19 9 72 64.323 .000<br />
(2) Internet 48 27 25 9.548 .008<br />
(3) Exhibitions and fairs 51 26 24 12.452 .002<br />
(4) Sales agents<br />
(5) Recommendation by<br />
54 22 25 17.613 .000<br />
business partners 61 26 13 35.032 .000<br />
(6) Former business<br />
relationship<br />
22 14 65 41.484 .000<br />
(7) Private contacts<br />
(e.g. family ties)<br />
8 12 81 93.935 .000<br />
Note: Importance is measured on a Likert scale with 1=very important to 5=not important, mean value indicated.<br />
Source: calculation based on own survey conducted in DFG SPP 1233 [2007]
18 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
ing their services to the firm (intangible), or<br />
they recommend a third party (transferable)<br />
(DIMAGGIO/LOUCH 1998). Firms save ex ante<br />
transaction costs for screening their environment<br />
for new customers and producers, collecting<br />
information and establishing the first<br />
contact, but they also hope to achieve better<br />
safeguards than in a formal process (POWELL<br />
1990; DIMAGGIO/LOUCH 1998; GRANOVETTER<br />
1985). Former experiences may be used as an<br />
indicator for future satisfaction (MACLEOD<br />
2006). If a producer has acquired a good reputation<br />
in a business network, it is treated as an<br />
asset which loses its value should the producer<br />
disappoint customers (MACLEOD 2006; ARAU-<br />
JO/ORNELAS 2007:3). As networks are reciprocal,<br />
firms are willing to repay favours. Preliminary<br />
empirical evidence was fo<strong>und</strong> in the<br />
study of GASTON/BELL (1988). They proved<br />
that two-thirds of investors in the informal capital<br />
market find investments through their networks.<br />
The most reliable sources are friends<br />
and business partners. SHILLER/POUND (1989)<br />
confirmed those findings. They fo<strong>und</strong> that the<br />
majority of purchasers of publicly traded common<br />
stocks buy based on information from<br />
friends and business associates. Networks are<br />
usually developed on an individual level, but<br />
are often transferred to a firm level. This does<br />
not skew empirical findings as long as firms<br />
are small and/or family-led. The owner and<br />
manager is the same person and the owner's<br />
network is identical to the firm's network. This<br />
mainly applies to small and medium enterprises<br />
(SME) in HK. In large firms with frequent<br />
changes in management positions, a distinction<br />
must be made between the networks of<br />
individuals and those of the firm.<br />
In conclusion, HK firms proved that contacting<br />
channels have not yet formalised completely,<br />
and that informal modes retain their importance.<br />
This is also in accordance with the theory<br />
outlined by ZENGER et al. (2002). Formal institutions<br />
do not necessarily go along with formal<br />
interactions, but provide room for the use<br />
of informal as well as formal actions.<br />
Selecting: It is expected that the contacting of<br />
customers and producers is carried out on a<br />
continual basis. A selection occurs if a new<br />
partner is needed. Selection processes are of<br />
Tab. 4: Importance of formal and informal selection criteria of HK firms for producers in<br />
equity cooperation and non-equity cooperation (in %)<br />
equity cooperation (n=17) non-equity cooperation (n=17) Chi² significance<br />
important moderate not important moderat not<br />
important important important important<br />
(1) Expertise<br />
(2) Good<br />
65 18 18 76 18 6 1.167 .558<br />
reputation<br />
(3) Good<br />
experiences<br />
in previous<br />
71 12 18 76 18 6 1.240 .538<br />
business<br />
(4) Get along<br />
with local<br />
workers/<br />
82 6 12 71 24 6 2.287 .319<br />
suppliers well<br />
(5) Get along<br />
with public<br />
29 35 35 24 41 35 .188 .910<br />
officials well<br />
(6) Existence<br />
of personal<br />
18 35 47 12 18 71 2.000 .368<br />
relationships 71 12 18 41 47 12 5.116 .077<br />
Note: Importance is measured on a Likert scale with 1=very important to 5=not important, mean value indicated.<br />
Source: calculation based on own survey conducted in DFG SPP 1233 [2007]
Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />
particular interest when firms look for new cooperation<br />
partners. MEYER et al. (2009) outlined<br />
that cooperation with PRD producers has<br />
become more important for HK firms in recent<br />
years. Therefore, the selection criteria for PRD<br />
producers in cooperation were analysed using<br />
the dimension ‘personalisation’ in the informality<br />
pattern. Selection criteria can range<br />
from very formal, without any involvement of<br />
personal assets, to very informal, which qualifies<br />
producers only because of personal relations.<br />
Expertise can be seen as an objective<br />
measurement of skills and is therefore very impersonal.<br />
A good reputation is based on a pool<br />
of subjective measurements and is therefore<br />
deemed to be impersonal, but not as impersonal<br />
as expertise. Positive experiences in previous<br />
business dealings are based on a firm's own<br />
subjective measurement of the producer's quality.<br />
It is linked to moderate personalisation. In<br />
contrast, selection criteria are more personal<br />
when they qualify producers to get along well<br />
with local workers, suppliers and public officials.<br />
When a producer is qualified because of<br />
a private connection, this counts as informal.<br />
For analysis, the focus is on cooperative relations,<br />
as they are concerned with the highest<br />
degree of mutual interaction and potentially informal<br />
traits. For simple reasons, there is a distinction<br />
between equity cooperation and nonequity<br />
cooperation of HK firms with PRD producers.<br />
Equity cooperation with Chinese firms<br />
was mandatory at the beginning of the transformation<br />
process and could be considered as<br />
the oldest mode of cooperation existing between<br />
HK firms and Chinese producers. Nonequity<br />
cooperation was a free-choice decision<br />
that appeared with the modernisation of Chinese<br />
laws. The differentiation between equity<br />
cooperation (e.g. joint ventures) and non-equity<br />
cooperation (e.g. loosely concluded cooperation<br />
agreements) provides interesting results<br />
about firms' preferences within those relationships<br />
and potential changes in cooperation. It<br />
can be seen, for example, whether personal relations<br />
still steer cooperation or whether they<br />
are equally important to other formal procedures.<br />
When looking at equity cooperation, Tab. 4<br />
shows that positive experience in previous<br />
business dealings is of the greatest importance<br />
(82 %), followed by a good reputation of producers<br />
and the existence of personal relationships<br />
(both 71 %). HK firms' selection criteria<br />
19<br />
for producers in equity cooperation are based<br />
on subjective quality measurements and personal<br />
relationships. Informal and moderately<br />
informal criteria are mainly applied. However,<br />
when turning to non-equity cooperation, expertise<br />
as an objective means of measuring the<br />
quality of producers is of the greatest importance,<br />
along with a good reputation (both<br />
76 %). The third most important factor is positive<br />
experience in previous business dealings<br />
(71 %). While some firms apparently need to<br />
smooth relationships to potential joint venture<br />
partners through informal modes, other firms<br />
working in non-equity cooperation set their<br />
priority on measurements of quality, for example<br />
personal relationships are much more important<br />
in equity than in non-equity relations.<br />
This also became significant in the Chi²-test.<br />
The findings showed that a successful partnership<br />
in non-equity cooperation is characterised<br />
by expertise and a good reputation of producers<br />
in combination with mutual <strong>und</strong>erstanding.<br />
In contrast, equity cooperation follows another<br />
strategy. It is mainly applied to running<br />
the business. This was the way in which HK<br />
firms were forced to work at the beginning of<br />
the Chinese opening policy. The way equity<br />
cooperation is seen by HK firms does not seem<br />
to have changed over recent years. There is an<br />
initial signal for a difference in importance of<br />
personal relations, and Guanxi might change<br />
from a purely personal to a business network.<br />
Moreover, it can be observed that in a modern<br />
non-equity relationship, HK firms balance formal<br />
and informal criteria instead of purely relying<br />
on informal ties. But to a certain extent,<br />
informality remains an opportunity. As these<br />
findings are only a preliminary sign, this issue<br />
definitely requires further research.<br />
In summary, the findings on contacting and selecting<br />
procedures of HK firms show, first, that<br />
personal relations are much more important<br />
when dealing with firms in China than with<br />
global customers, which is an expression of the<br />
influence of the institutional setting. But second,<br />
it could be shown that HK firms still use<br />
informal modes to contact and select global<br />
customers, even though the institutional environment<br />
would allow a reliance on formal<br />
modes only. This confirms again that a certain<br />
degree of informalisation smoothes business<br />
relations. HK firms tend to combine formal and<br />
informal modes in order to succeed. Formal<br />
and informal modes are not mutually exclu-
20 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
sive, but rather complement each other.<br />
MILLINGTON et al. (2006) also worked on the<br />
identification process of Chinese partners.<br />
Their findings also show that personal connections,<br />
and in particular guanxi, helped UK and<br />
US-invested manufacturers in China to select<br />
producers. They also observed, however, that<br />
guanxi nowadays consists of business rather<br />
than family and community connections.<br />
Contractual arrangements with customers<br />
and producers<br />
Precision and form of contracts: Once firms<br />
have contacted and selected their potential customers<br />
and producers, they have to settle transaction-specific<br />
details. This section provides<br />
evidence on how contractual arrangements are<br />
concluded. Two dimensions of informality are<br />
analysed: the form of agreements (written to<br />
verbal) and precision (precise to open-ended).<br />
Interviews with lawyers in the GPRD indicated<br />
that the following points require attention<br />
when contracts are concluded: product specification,<br />
quantity, price, delivery time, agreement<br />
on exclusivity, penalties for breach of<br />
contract.<br />
The proportions of HK firms which fix all<br />
points in contracts are shown in Tab. 5 (see<br />
columns ‘precision of contracts’). If points are<br />
fixed in contract, this could be in written form,<br />
verbal form or both (see columns ‘form of contracts’).<br />
The more open-ended an agreement is<br />
and the more details are agreed on verbally, the<br />
greater the informal character of a contractual<br />
Tab. 5: Preciseness and form of framework agreements of HK firms<br />
arrangement is. Again, a comparison is made<br />
between HK firms’ contractual organisation to<br />
global customers and to producers in the PRD.<br />
When looking at the precision as a dimension<br />
of informality, the findings show that more<br />
than three quarters of the necessary details are<br />
fixed before the actual production process<br />
starts. Only a small proportion of firms have<br />
imprecise and therefore informal contracts. A<br />
look at how points are fixed, the form of agreements,<br />
indicates that HK firms mainly keep to<br />
formal modes, although there is a slight trend<br />
towards more informal agreements with PRD<br />
producers. If points are agreed on in advance,<br />
the majority of HK firms fix important points<br />
in written form. In customer relations, an average<br />
of 51 % of HK firms reported fixing all<br />
points in writing, while in producer relations,<br />
the figure was 46 %. An exclusively verbal<br />
agreement is only concluded by a very small<br />
number of firms (customers: 7 %, producers:<br />
5 %). In producer relations, the combination of<br />
both written and verbal agreements is preferred<br />
by about one quarter of the firms, while in customer<br />
relations, the number drops to 20 %.<br />
Comparing customer and producer relations, it<br />
becomes clear that the number of written details<br />
in contracts is slightly higher with customers<br />
than with producers.<br />
HK firms apply informal modes when contacting<br />
and selecting customers and producers, but<br />
when it comes to contractual arrangements,<br />
they mostly do not rely on trust and a hand<br />
Customers (n=27) Producers (n=38)<br />
Precision of contracts Precision of contracts<br />
sum Form of contracts sum Form of contracts<br />
not fixed fixeda written/verbal/both not fixed fixeda written/verbal/both<br />
Product specification 100 7 93 → 63 7 22 100 16 84 → 50 3 32<br />
Quantity of products 100 22 78 → 48 7 22 100 13 87 → 55 0 32<br />
Price of products 100 15 85 → 63 4 19 100 16 84 → 53 3 29<br />
Delivery time<br />
Agreement on<br />
100 15 85 → 59 7 19 100 13 87 → 58 5 24<br />
exclusivity<br />
Penalties for<br />
100 37 63 → 33 7 22 100 47 53 → 32 5 16<br />
breach of contracts 100 33 67 → 41 7 19 100 42 58 → 26 16 16<br />
Mean 100 22 78 → 51 7 20 100 25 75 → 46 5 25<br />
a sum of shares written, verbal and both<br />
Source: calculation based on own survey conducted in DFG SPP 1233 [2007]
Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />
shake, but prefer written agreements. When<br />
disputes occur, a written document is of higher<br />
value than a person's word. What could not be<br />
proven in the quantitative data, but has been<br />
derived from the interviews, is that although<br />
points are fixed in a written form, those written<br />
contracts are not comparable to what Westerners<br />
intuitively associate with written contracts.<br />
Family ties and long-term business relationships<br />
are reasons for non-dedicated contracts.<br />
Lawyers have often experienced that Chinese<br />
firms have only rudimentary contracts, even<br />
for large projects. Often, a one-page contract is<br />
concluded covering the main points, but it is<br />
not proofed by lawyers. Those contracts are<br />
very difficult to enforce by law in the case of<br />
disputes. LEE (1997, 189) shows that one third<br />
of HK managers rely on verbal contracts.<br />
Informal contracts indicate greater flexibility:<br />
An important contribution of this work is to<br />
study the correlation of informality and flexibility.<br />
Although HK firms indeed indicated<br />
having formal contracts, there is some evidence<br />
for informal contracting as well. Initial<br />
proof of whether informal contracts lead to<br />
quicker response and greater flexibility can be<br />
considered as an answer to the question of<br />
whether informality serves as necessity or opportunity.<br />
It must be investigated as to whether<br />
informal contracts are perhaps of even greater<br />
advantage than formal contracts with respect to<br />
the time of negotiation. In order to prove the<br />
correlation of informality and flexibility, evidence<br />
must be fo<strong>und</strong> of informal contracts<br />
leaving more leeway for firms to arrange the<br />
actual order, saving them extra time and reducing<br />
transaction costs. Flexibility in contractual<br />
arrangements was measured according to the<br />
time in days required by firms to negotiate details<br />
before the production process could start.<br />
What effect informal contracts have on the<br />
time between the beginning of negotiations and<br />
the start of production in contrast to formal<br />
contracts is shown in Tab. 6, distinguishing between<br />
customers and producers. HK firms<br />
which have informal contracts with their pro-<br />
21<br />
ducers indicated a shorter negotiation time on<br />
average than firms with formal contracts (three<br />
days instead of five days). In this case, informal<br />
contracts seem to allow more leeway for<br />
final negotiation, which reduces negotiation<br />
time before production can start. In a rapidly<br />
changing business environment, the costs of<br />
drawing up a comprehensive contract are extremely<br />
high. PRD firms in particular, as component<br />
suppliers of HK firms, suffer from permanently<br />
changing market conditions and poor<br />
forecasting systems, which increases their need<br />
for flexibility. When producers are located<br />
within the PRD, informality in contractual<br />
arrangements works well in combination with<br />
spatial proximity and guanxi, as information<br />
may be verbally agreed on and revised. This<br />
finding cannot yet be generalised due to the<br />
low number of cases. Moreover, the difference<br />
between three and five days is not significant.<br />
This finding only serves as an initial signal for<br />
the advantages of informal behaviour, but definitely<br />
needs further investigation.<br />
Informal agreements with customers reduce<br />
the time required for negotiation when an actual<br />
order is placed from seven days to six days.<br />
It seems to be more difficult to agree upon<br />
actual orders when the contract is informally<br />
organised in long-distance customer relationships,<br />
because the absolute negotiation time is<br />
longer. Again, due to the low number of cases,<br />
the findings cannot be generalised. Potential<br />
explanations for this observation could be that<br />
forecasting systems of HK firms are better and<br />
the need for flexibility is lower, therefore informal<br />
agreements are of advantage, but formal<br />
agreements can hold their own in terms of<br />
speed. As HK firms and international customers<br />
work in a complete institutional environment,<br />
transaction costs for concluding written<br />
contracts are lower. Additionally, this<br />
seems to be of advantage for the enforcement<br />
of contracts, as the legal system provides firms<br />
with sufficient enforcement mechanisms.<br />
LYONS (1994) investigated firms in France and<br />
fo<strong>und</strong> that contracts between firms usually tend<br />
Tab. 6: Effects of formal and informal framework agreements on the negotiation time<br />
Customers Producers<br />
n Time of negotiation n Time of negotiation<br />
Formal Contract 18 7 days 23 5 days<br />
Informal Contract 9 6 days 15 3 days<br />
Source: calculation based on own survey conducted in DFG SPP 1233 [2007]
22 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
to be informalised when they work in rapidly<br />
changing business environments, because the<br />
costs of drawing up a comprehensive contract<br />
are too high.<br />
Conclusion<br />
The aim of this paper was to show the <strong>und</strong>erestimated<br />
importance of informal interactions<br />
for business operations in transitional economies,<br />
which serve more purposes than simply<br />
to replace dysfunctional formal rules. The<br />
GPRD, with its distinct institutional setting,<br />
served as an example to prove to what extent<br />
informality serves as an opportunity or as a necessity.<br />
Informal ties in firm networks are<br />
maintained to some extent due to their high efficiency,<br />
even if formal institutions are developed<br />
to international standards. Informal interactions<br />
turned out not only to be considered<br />
as a substitute for missing formal rules, but as<br />
a complement. A firm survey in HK in 2008<br />
delivered the empirical data to prove the hypotheses.<br />
104 small and medium-sized firms<br />
were interviewed. As the quality of the survey<br />
was of great importance, the return rate was<br />
only 5 %. This also resulted in a low number of<br />
cases for analysing specific questions. As this<br />
study is of an explorative nature, representative<br />
results were not aimed for. The findings cannot<br />
be generalised, but they deliver initial signals<br />
for a positive assessment of informality, which<br />
should be considered for further research.<br />
It could be proven that HK firms apply a lower<br />
degree of informalisation in relations with<br />
global customers than with local producers<br />
when contacting and selecting partners as well<br />
as designing contracts (hypothesis 1). However,<br />
when firms work with producers in the<br />
PRD, they do not rely purely on informal ties,<br />
but have a healthy balance of formal and informal<br />
behaviour (hypothesis 2). For contacting<br />
and selecting partners, firms use their networks<br />
instead of the formal procedure of quality<br />
assessment. Contracts are mainly fixed in<br />
writing, but they only cover the most important<br />
details, which are subject to negotiation afterwards.<br />
It turned out that HK firms use informal<br />
ties to organise business with global customers<br />
as well. They do not only use informality as a<br />
necessity in dealing with Chinese firms, but<br />
also see it as an opportunity to increase their<br />
variety of modes to do business. Therefore, it<br />
can be expected that the world’s factory for<br />
electronic products in the GPRD will continue<br />
to rely on informal ties between firms, even if<br />
China makes an effort to improve its formal institutional<br />
environment. In order to prove this,<br />
further research is needed to see whether informal<br />
ties in reality overcome the discussion<br />
about the influence of institutions on firms’ behaviour,<br />
and to what extent. There were also<br />
empirical signals confirming hypothesis 3. The<br />
data showed that informal contracting reduces<br />
the time of negotiating contracts and therefore<br />
increases flexibility. This is initial proof for informality<br />
providing an opportunity for firms.<br />
Informality is not limited to necessity. As the<br />
number of cases is low, further investigation is<br />
required here.<br />
Without being a newly introduced business<br />
concept to firms in the GPRD, the strategic application<br />
of informal interaction may be an innovative<br />
approach to Western firms. With this<br />
study having stepped forward in identifying the<br />
relevance of informal interactions, a so<strong>und</strong> empirical<br />
analysis is desirable in order to clarify<br />
the patterns and mechanisms in more detail.<br />
Acknowledgement<br />
I would like to thank my colleague Daniel Schiller for<br />
the fruitful discussions and joint development of the<br />
idea to study informality from the perspective of necessity<br />
and opportunity. This paper is the result of our idea.<br />
Moreover, I would like to thank the anonymous reviewer<br />
for her/his helpful comments on earlier versions of<br />
the paper. F<strong>und</strong>ing for this research was received from<br />
the German Research Fo<strong>und</strong>ation (DFG) within the<br />
Priority Programme (SPP 1233) “Megacities-Megachallenge<br />
– the informal dynamics of global change”<br />
<strong>und</strong>er grant RE 1720/8-1.<br />
References<br />
ANGELES, R./NATH, R. (2000): An empirical study of<br />
EDI trading partner selection criteria in customer-supplier<br />
relationships. In: Information & Management,<br />
(37)5, 241-255.<br />
ARAUJO, L./ORNELAS, E. (2007): Trust-based trade.<br />
London. (CEP Discussion Paper No 820, Centre for<br />
Economic Performance, London School of Economics<br />
and Political Science).<br />
BAKER, W. E. (2000): Achieving success through social<br />
capital. Tapping the hidden resources in your personal<br />
and business networks. San Francisco.<br />
BOSCHMA, R./FRENKEN K. (2009): Some notes on institutions<br />
in evolutionary economic geography. In: Economic<br />
Geography, (82)5, 151-158.
Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />
BOSCHMA, R./FRENKEN K. (2006): Why is economic geography<br />
not an evolutionary science? Towards an evolutionary<br />
economic geography. In: Journal of Economic<br />
Geography, 6, 273-302.<br />
BURT, R. S. (1992): Structural holes: the social structure<br />
of competition. Cambridge.<br />
CANFEI, H./WEI, Y.D./ XIUZHEN, X. (2008): Globalization,<br />
institutional change, and industrial location. Economic<br />
transition and industrial concentration in China.<br />
In: Regional Studies, (42)7, 923-945.<br />
COLEMAN, J.S. (1988): Social capital in the creation of<br />
human-capital. In: American Journal of Sociology, 94,<br />
95-120.<br />
COLEMAN, J.S. (1990): The fo<strong>und</strong>ations of social theory.<br />
Cambridge.<br />
DIMAGGIO, P./LOUCH, H. (1998): Socially embedded<br />
consumer transactions. For what kinds of purchases do<br />
people most often use networks? In: American Sociological<br />
Review, (63)5, 619-637.<br />
DUNNING, J. H./KIM, C. (2007): The cultural roots of<br />
Guanxi. An exploratory study. In: World Economy,<br />
(30)2, 329-341.<br />
DUYSTERS, G./KOK, G./VAANDRAGER, M. (1999): Crafting<br />
successful strategic technology partnerships. In:<br />
R&D Management, (29)4, 343-351.<br />
ERNST, D. (2004): Global production networks in East<br />
Asia's electronics industry and upgrading prospects in<br />
Malaysia. In: Yusuf, S./Altaf, M.A./Nabeshima, K.<br />
(Eds.): Global production networking and technological<br />
change in East Asia. Washington, 8-157.<br />
ETZOLD, B./KECK, M./BOHLE, H.-G./ZINGEL, W.-P.<br />
(2009): Informality as agency. Negotiating food security<br />
in Dhaka. In: Die Erde, (140)1, 1-22.<br />
FAN, Y. (2002): Questioning guanxi. Definition, classification<br />
and implications. In: International Business Review,<br />
11, 543-561.<br />
FEARON, J.D./LAITIN, D.D. (1996): Explaining interethnic<br />
cooperation. In: American Political Science Review,<br />
(90)4, 715-735.<br />
GASTON, R. J./BELL, S. (1988): The informal supply of<br />
capital. London. (Tech. report, Office of Economic Research,<br />
U.S. Small Business Administration).<br />
GERTLER, M. (2010): Rules of the game: The place of<br />
institutions in regional economic change. In: Regional<br />
Studies, (44)1, 1-15.<br />
GRANOVETTER, M. (1973): Strength of weak ties. In:<br />
American Journal of Sociology, (78)6, 1360-1380.<br />
GRANOVETTER,, M. (1985): Economic-action and socialstructure.<br />
The problem of embeddedness. In: American<br />
Journal of Sociology, (91)3, 481-510.<br />
Guangdong Provincial Bureau of Statistics (2006):<br />
Guangdong statistical yearbook 2006. (China Statistics<br />
Press).<br />
Guangdong Provincial Bureau of Statistics (2007):<br />
Guangdong statistical yearbook 2007. (China Statistics<br />
Press).<br />
HART, O./MOORE, J. (2004): Agreeing now to agree later.<br />
Contracts that rule out but do not rule. (China Statis-<br />
23<br />
tics Press) (Harvard Law and Economics Discussion Paper<br />
No. 465; Harvard <strong>Institut</strong>e of Econ. Research Disc.<br />
Paper 2032).<br />
HITT, M.A./DACIN, M.T./LEVITAS, E./ARREGLE,<br />
J.L./BORZA, A. (2000): Partner selection in emerging<br />
and developed market contexts. Resource-based and organizational<br />
learning perspectives. In: Academy of<br />
Management Journal, (43)3, 449-467.<br />
HUMPHREY, R. H./ASHFORTH, B.E. (2000): Buyer-supplier<br />
alliances in the automobile industry. How exitvoice<br />
strategies influence interpersonal relationships.<br />
In: Journal of Organizational Behavior, (21)6, 713-730.<br />
LEE, M.-K. (1997): The flexibility of the Hong Kong<br />
manufacturing sector. In: China Information, (12)1/2,<br />
189-214.<br />
LI, P.P. (2007): Social tie, social capital, and social behaviour.<br />
Toward an integrative model of informal exchange.<br />
In: Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24,<br />
227-246.<br />
LUO, Y./CHEN, M. (1997): Does guanxi influence firm<br />
performance. In: Asia Pacific Journal of Management,<br />
14, 1-16.<br />
LYONS, B.R. (1994): Contracts and specific investment.<br />
An empirical test of transaction cost theory. In: Journal<br />
of Economics and Management Strategy, (3)2, 257-278.<br />
MACAULAY, S. (1963): Non-contractual relations in<br />
business. A preliminary-study. In: American Sociological<br />
Review, (28)1, 55-67.<br />
MACLEOD, W.B. (2006): Reputations, relationships and<br />
the enforcement of incomplete contracts. Ney York.<br />
(Center for Economic Studies & <strong>Institut</strong>e for Economic<br />
Research, Working Paper 1730).<br />
MASTEN, E.S. (2000): Contractual choice. In: Boukaert,<br />
B./De Geest, G. (Eds.): Encyclopedia of Law and Economics.<br />
Cheltenham, 25-45.<br />
MENARD, C. (2004): The economics of hybrid organizations.<br />
In: Journal of <strong>Institut</strong>ional and Theoretical Economics,<br />
(160)3, 345-376.<br />
MEYER, S./SCHILLER, D./REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2009): The<br />
Janus-faced economy: Hong Kong firms as intermediaries<br />
between global customers and local producers in<br />
the electronics industry. In: Tijdschrift voor economische<br />
en sociale geografie, (100)2, 224-235.<br />
Millington, A./Eberhardt, M./Wilkinson, B. (2006):<br />
Guanxi and supplier search mechanisms in China. In:<br />
Human Relations, (59)4, 505-531.<br />
MISZTAL, B. (2000): Informality. Social theory and contemporary<br />
practice. London.<br />
NEE, V. (1992): Organizational dynamics of market<br />
transition. Hybrid forms, property-rights, and mixed<br />
economy in China. In: Administrative Science Quarterly,<br />
(37)1, 1-27.<br />
NORTH, D. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change and<br />
economic performance. Cambridge.<br />
PARK, S.H./LUO, Y.D. (2001): Guanxi and organizational<br />
dynamics. Organizational networking in Chinese<br />
firms. In: Strategic Management Journal, (22)5, 455-<br />
477.
24 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
PIDDUCK, A.B. (2006): Issues in supplier partner selection.<br />
In: Journal of Enterprise Information Management,<br />
(19)3, 262-276.<br />
POWELL, W.W. (1990): Neither market nor hierarchy.<br />
Network forms of organization. In: Research in Organizational<br />
Behavior, 12, 295-336.<br />
PUTNAM, R.D. (1993): Making democracy work. Civic<br />
traditions in modern Italy. Princeton.<br />
PUTNAM, R.D. (2000): Bowling alone. The collapse and<br />
revival of American community. New York.<br />
RICHTER, R./FURUBOTN, E. (1996): Neue <strong>Institut</strong>ionenökonomik.<br />
Eine Einführung <strong>und</strong> kritische Würdigung.<br />
Tübingen.<br />
SAFFU, K./MAMMAN, A. (2000): Mechanics, problems<br />
and contributions of tertiary strategic alliances. The case<br />
of 22 Australian universities. In: Library Consortium<br />
Management: An International Journal, (2)2, 44-53.<br />
SEGAL, I. (1999): Complexity and renegotiation. A fo<strong>und</strong>ation<br />
for incomplete contracts. In: Review of Economic<br />
Studies, (66)1, 57-82.<br />
SHILLER, R.J./POUND, J. (1989): Survey evidence on diffusion<br />
of interest and information among investors. In: Journal<br />
of Economic Behavior & Organization, (1)1, 47-66.<br />
SINDZINGRE, A. (2006): The relevance of the concepts of<br />
formality and informality. A theoretical appraisal. In:<br />
Guha-Khasnobis, B./Kanbur, R./Ostrom, E. (Eds.):<br />
Linking the formal and informal economy. Concepts<br />
and policies. Oxford, 58-74.<br />
WILLIAMSON, O. (2000): The new institutional economics.<br />
Taking stock, looking ahead. In: Journal of Economic<br />
Literature, (38)3, 595-613.<br />
XIN, K.R./PEARCE, J.L. (1996): Guanxi: Connections as<br />
substitutes for formal institutional support. In: Academy<br />
of Management Journal, (39)6, 1641-1658.<br />
YEUNG, H.W. C., LIN, G.C.S. (2003) Theorizing economic<br />
geographies of Asia. In: Economic Geography,<br />
(79)2, 107-128.<br />
ZENGER, T.R./LAZZARINI, S.G./POPPO, L. (2002): Informal<br />
and formal organization in new institutional economics.<br />
In: New <strong>Institut</strong>ionalism in Strategic Management,<br />
19, 277-305.<br />
ZHANG, Y./ZHANG, Z.G. (2006): Guanxi and organizational<br />
dynamics in China. A link between individual and<br />
organizational levels. In: Journal of Business Ethics,<br />
(67)4, 375-392.
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 25-42<br />
Frank Bickenbach/ Wan-Hsin Liu, Kiel<br />
Firm characteristics and informal governance of business operations<br />
in the Pearl River Delta, China<br />
Abstract: This paper describes the Chinese economic and institutional reform process as a gradual<br />
transition of an informal, relation-based governance system into a more formal and rule-based<br />
governance system. The consequences of macro-level institutional reforms on the importance of<br />
personal relationships for the firm-level governance of business operations are discussed. Theoretical<br />
considerations suggest that in a transition economy such as China companies’ incentives to<br />
reduce the reliance on personal relationships should depend on firm characteristics such as the age,<br />
size and the internationalization of the firm. We confront these suppositions with empirical data<br />
obtained from a company survey performed among 222 companies in the electronics industry operating<br />
in the Pearl River Delta, China. From this we obtain some, though often weak, evidence<br />
in favor of the suppositions.<br />
Keywords: formal and informal institutions, relation-based governance, firm characteristics,<br />
China, company survey<br />
JEL classification: L20, L63, P0<br />
Introduction<br />
Over the last three decades, China has recorded<br />
very high economic growth rates and developed<br />
into the second largest economy in the<br />
world. This remarkable growth was accompanied<br />
and fueled by continuing reforms of formal<br />
legal and market institutions which together<br />
led to substantial changes in the institutional<br />
environment in which business firms operate in<br />
China. This reform process may be viewed as a<br />
gradual transformation of the Chinese economy<br />
from an informal, relation-based governance<br />
system to a more formal and rule-based<br />
governance system (LI 2004; LI/PARK/LI<br />
2004).<br />
The importance and pervasive use of personal<br />
relationships in daily social and business life in<br />
China has attracted considerable attention<br />
among researchers from various disciplines.<br />
There has in particular been a growing economics<br />
and management literature on the role<br />
of personal relationships for doing business in<br />
China. Most of the empirical studies of that literature<br />
are based on surveys among Chinese<br />
managers or foreign managers with some experience<br />
in Chinese business (e.g. XIN/PEARCE<br />
1996; DAVIES/LEUNG/LUK/WONG 1995; LUO<br />
1997; PARK/LUO 2001). Generally, the survey<br />
results confirm the importance of personal relationships<br />
with other managers and/or with<br />
government officials (for a summary see LAN-<br />
GENBERG 2007, LUO 2007). In a study related to<br />
the present one, BICKENBACH/LIU (2010) confirm<br />
this general observation for Hong Kong<br />
based companies with operations in the Pearl<br />
River Delta (PRD) 1 , China. They also find evidence<br />
showing that personal relationships are<br />
less important than other more objective criteria<br />
for these companies’ decisions on business<br />
partners (and business locations). This result<br />
may be interpreted as an indication that the improvements<br />
in the formal institutional environment<br />
induce companies operating in current<br />
China to gradually reduce their predominant<br />
reliance on informal relation-based governance<br />
instruments and turn to make increased use of<br />
rule-based governance instruments such as formal<br />
contracting and public information institutions.<br />
Theoretical considerations suggest that, in a<br />
transition economy such as China, not all companies<br />
will have equally strong incentives to
26 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
move from informal relation-based to more<br />
formal, rule-based forms of governance. The<br />
incentives to reduce the reliance on personal<br />
relations will be stronger, in particular, for older,<br />
larger and faster growing firms. The same<br />
may be expected to be true for companies with<br />
more international business contacts (international<br />
suppliers or customers) or larger foreign<br />
ownership interests. This paper outlines the<br />
theoretical considerations <strong>und</strong>erlying these<br />
suppositions and confronts them with data obtained<br />
from a company survey that was done<br />
among 222 companies in the electronics industry<br />
operating in the PRD, China.<br />
In the following we briefly present the institutional<br />
economics perspective on the nature of<br />
informal, relation-based and formal, rule-based<br />
modes of governance and their comparative<br />
(dis)advantages, both at the aggregate and at<br />
the firm level and derive our core suppositions<br />
regarding the relation between firm characteristics<br />
and firms’ incentives to use of personal<br />
relationships for doing business in a “transition”<br />
economy. Then we outline the changing<br />
institutional environment in China in general<br />
and in the PRD in particular and we discuss the<br />
empirical results regarding the relation between<br />
firm characteristics and the role of personal<br />
relationships for doing business in the<br />
PRD.<br />
Theoretical considerations<br />
<strong>Institut</strong>ions, i.e. rules and instruments to enforce<br />
these rules, matter for the efficiency of<br />
human exchange (NORTH 1990). By defining<br />
and protecting property rights, enforcing contracts,<br />
and providing reliable information, well<br />
functioning (economic) institutions can reduce<br />
the risks and transaction costs of investment<br />
and exchange. These institutions can be formal<br />
or informal. Formal institutions include political,<br />
judicial and economic rules, ranging from<br />
written constitutions and statutory laws to specific<br />
regulations and to individual contracts.<br />
Informal institutions include the social and religious<br />
norms, traditions and codes of conduct<br />
and the social networks that exist in a society<br />
(NORTH 1990, 36, 47). Two levels of institutions<br />
are to be distinguished: the institutional<br />
environment and institutional arrangements.<br />
The institutional environment is the overarching<br />
framework of political, social and legal<br />
rules and constraints that define the context in<br />
which economic and social interaction takes<br />
place. Within this framework, parties to a specific<br />
exchange set up institutional arrangements,<br />
i.e., formal and informal (micro-level)<br />
rules and forms of contracts that govern the<br />
way in which they cooperate and/or compete<br />
(WILLIAMSON 1996, 378).<br />
Three elements of the institutional environment,<br />
in particular, are of great importance for<br />
the level and the organization of economic exchange<br />
of an economy: contracting institutions,<br />
property rights institutions and information<br />
institutions. Contracting institutions are<br />
the rules that support the conclusion and the<br />
enforcement of contracts between (private)<br />
economic agents (ACEMOGLU/JOHNSON 2005,<br />
955). They affect the costs of drafting and enforcing<br />
contracts and consequently the type of<br />
contracts and transactions realized. Property<br />
rights institutions are the rules that protect (the<br />
returns to) the assets held by economic agents<br />
against expropriation by others, in particular,<br />
by the government and politically powerful<br />
elites (ACEMOGLU/JOHNSON 2005, 955; GREIF<br />
2005, 728). They affect the risk of direct government<br />
expropriation as well as the level to<br />
which regulations and public decisions determine<br />
a level playing field for all economic actors<br />
or favor and protect a small elite with close<br />
relationships with the government. Information<br />
institutions are public or private institutions<br />
for gathering and distributing information.<br />
They affect the amount and the quality of<br />
information available to economic actors (and<br />
public agents) and impact, in particular, the<br />
cost of screening (potential) business partners<br />
and of monitoring their performance. 2<br />
There are substantial differences between societies<br />
in the nature and sophistication of their<br />
basic institutions and in the degree to which<br />
they are able to reduce the transaction costs<br />
and the risks associated with economic exchange<br />
and investments in private assets. In<br />
Western societies, over time, a complex system<br />
of formal institutions for public information<br />
provision, contract enforcement and property<br />
rights protection has been devised, on which<br />
people can build for governing economic exchanges.<br />
Many of these formal institutions are<br />
non-existent, weak or poorly devised in less<br />
developed countries (BARDHAN 2005, 512). To<br />
govern economic exchanges people in these<br />
countries tend to rely more on informal institu-
Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 27<br />
tions and personal relations, e.g., guanxi in<br />
China (LI/PARK/LI 2004, 63).<br />
Based on this general observation, we may<br />
distinguish for analytical purposes between<br />
two modes of governance systems: relationbased<br />
and rule-based governance systems (LI<br />
2003; LI/PARK/LI 2004; DIXIT 2004). The two<br />
systems differ both at the macro-level of the<br />
institutional environment and at the micro-level<br />
of the institutional arrangements chosen to<br />
govern individual transactions between economic<br />
agents. These differences have profo<strong>und</strong><br />
implications for the nature and size of<br />
transaction costs <strong>und</strong>er the two governance<br />
systems.<br />
In a rule-based governance system public rules<br />
(laws and regulations) and state policies are<br />
transparent, fair, and universally applied and<br />
economic transactions are largely based on impersonal<br />
and explicit formal contracts. Both,<br />
public rules and private contracts can be impartially<br />
enforced by the executive and the<br />
court system (LI 2003, 655; LI/PARK/LI 2004,<br />
64). Economic agents have access to highquality<br />
and verifiable business information<br />
provided through a broad range of well established<br />
public information institutions (e.g. accounting<br />
and auditing rules, credit information<br />
institutions). This reduces the costs of screening<br />
and monitoring (potential) business partners<br />
and of enforcing business contracts (LI<br />
2003, 657).<br />
In a relation-based governance system, by contrast,<br />
public rules tend to be unfair and opaque,<br />
and the state is unable to enforce these rules<br />
impartially (LI /PARK /LI 2004, 64). Courts,<br />
due to the lack of independence and/or competence,<br />
are generally not able to enforce public<br />
rules or private contracts effectively. Most<br />
transactions between business partners are<br />
governed by personal and implicit agreements<br />
that are enforced outside the courtrooms (LI<br />
2003, 652). Publicly available information<br />
about (potential) business partners is rare and<br />
generally of low-quality. Key information<br />
about business partners has to be derived from<br />
personal relations. Information about business<br />
partners and business relationships tends to remain<br />
personal, and relational, i.e., mutually<br />
observable to the two transaction partners but<br />
unverifiable by people outside the relationship<br />
(LI/PARK/LI 2004, 64, 69; LI 2004, 108). 3<br />
It is widely recognized that the importance and<br />
the relative efficiency of formal institutions<br />
and rule-based governance increases relative to<br />
that of informal institution and relation-based<br />
governance as the scope of market exchange<br />
broadens and deepens (see NORTH 1990; LII<br />
2003; DIXIT 2004; LI/PARK/LI 2004). Relationbased<br />
governance systems work well in small<br />
or/and well-knit groups, whereas efficient exchange<br />
relations in large groups require more<br />
formal institutions for information dissemination<br />
and enforcement. At the aggregate level<br />
relation-based governance is associated with<br />
comparatively low fixed costs as it avoids the<br />
high fixed costs of developing elaborate formal<br />
public information and contracting institutions.<br />
At the level of individual exchanges, parties<br />
with existing personal relationships will find<br />
relation-based governance to be less costly as it<br />
saves the costs of legal enforcement and information<br />
verification. However, relation-based<br />
governance exhibits comparatively high and<br />
increasing costs of extending business to new<br />
business partners. Extending business will increasingly<br />
require establishing relations with<br />
persons, to which agents have a priori only<br />
weak or no private relations which raises the<br />
costs of searching for competent and reliable<br />
partners and of establishing personal relations<br />
with them.<br />
A rule-based governance system, in contrast,<br />
involves large fixed costs for establishing the<br />
necessary legal and informational infrastructure.<br />
However, once the necessary information<br />
and contracting institutions have been established<br />
the marginal costs of screening potential<br />
business partners and of negotiating and enforcing<br />
an (additional) contract between an<br />
(additional) pair of transaction parties, including<br />
strangers, are comparatively low due to the<br />
quality of publicly available information and<br />
the fact that the contracts are explicit, impersonal,<br />
and standardized (LI 2003, 657;<br />
LI/PARK/LI 2004, 65). As the scale and scope<br />
of the economy increases, the fixed costs of establishing<br />
a rule-based governance system can<br />
be spread over a larger number of transactions,<br />
thus lowering the average costs. Eventually an<br />
expanding economy will reach a point where<br />
the average transaction costs are smaller <strong>und</strong>er<br />
rule-based governance than <strong>und</strong>er relationbased<br />
governance and it would be advantageous<br />
for society to develop an institutional environment<br />
that supports rule-based governance.
28 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
The transition of an economy from a (more) relation-based<br />
to a (more) rule-based governance<br />
system will generally be a gradual and slow<br />
process. The basic informal institutions that exist<br />
in a society are often embedded in cultural<br />
traditions and moral value systems. They therefore<br />
possess inertia that slows the pace of institutional<br />
change (ZENGER/LAZZARINI/POPPO<br />
2002, 283 f.). 4 Even the effects of occasional<br />
broad and fast changes of formal institutions<br />
may be limited by tensions between the new<br />
formal rules and existing informal rules that respond<br />
only gradually to changes in the formal<br />
institutions. These tensions may <strong>und</strong>ermine<br />
compliance with formal rules and may create a<br />
lag between the implementation of a new formal<br />
institutional structure and its overall functionality<br />
(ZENGER/LAZZARINI/POPPO 2002, 283<br />
f.; NORTH 1990, 91). Simply issuing new, Western-type,<br />
business laws and formal institutions<br />
may thus not be sufficient to substantially improve<br />
the quality of public information, of legal<br />
contract enforcement and of the effective<br />
protection of property rights. And even if the<br />
new formal institutions work reasonably well,<br />
persistent cultural norms may still induce<br />
(some) economic agents at the micro-level to<br />
stick to the use of relation-based forms of governance.<br />
This is true, in particular, where the<br />
cost advantage of rule-based governance is still<br />
relatively small (and competitive pressures are<br />
not too strong).<br />
The theoretical considerations about the working<br />
and the (relative) costs and benefits of the<br />
two modes of governance suggest, that firms’<br />
incentives to move from relation-based to rulebased<br />
governance should depend on a number<br />
of firm characteristics, such as the size and the<br />
growth performance of the firm, its age, its<br />
ownership and the degree of its integration into<br />
national and international markets. The marginal<br />
cost of relation-based governance will<br />
generally be higher for large firms than for<br />
small firms. At the same time it will be easier<br />
for them to bear the firm-level fixed costs of<br />
rule-based governance – such as the costs of<br />
introducing new accounting and auditing systems<br />
or of acquiring the skills necessary to formulate<br />
and manage externally enforceable contracts.<br />
We should therefore expect that large<br />
firms have a greater propensity to engage in<br />
rule-based governance than small firms. Similarly,<br />
as the development of personal relations<br />
to new business partners is costly and timeconsuming,<br />
firms that are growing quickly in<br />
size and in the number of business partners will<br />
have greater incentives to reduce their reliance<br />
on personal relationships. Firms that are able<br />
and willing to make use of formal, rule-based<br />
mechanisms for searching and screening new<br />
business partners and managing and enforcing<br />
contractual agreements will find it easier to<br />
quickly expand the number of their business<br />
partners and will thus be able to grow faster.<br />
The age of a firm is certainly correlated with its<br />
size and possibly with its growth rate. The age<br />
of a firm will therefore have an indirect effect<br />
on its incentives to use rule-based governance<br />
mechanisms. The age of a firm can be expected<br />
to also have a direct influence on these incentives,<br />
however. Old-established firms will<br />
have accumulated substantial experience with<br />
relation-based governance and will already<br />
have established long-term personal relationships<br />
with a number of business partners and<br />
possibly public officials as well. Even as institutions<br />
of rule-based governance get gradually<br />
established at the level of the institutional environment,<br />
these firms will have an interest to<br />
continue to make use of their existing relationships,<br />
though it may become increasingly difficult<br />
to sustain these relationships as switching<br />
business partners becomes easier during the<br />
transition. At the same time established firms<br />
may have built up a public reputation as reliable<br />
business partners which allows them to<br />
get into business with new partners more easily.<br />
By contrast, even with improving information<br />
institutions new firms will generally have<br />
great difficulties signalling reliability and competence.<br />
At least with respect to getting into<br />
contact with new business partners existing<br />
personal relations with family members or<br />
friends (or early business partners) can thus be<br />
expected to be more important for young firms<br />
than for old-established ones. As to the importance<br />
of personal relations for doing business<br />
in general there is no clear conjecture about the<br />
role of firm age, however. On the one hand it<br />
will be very difficult for young firms to establish<br />
themselves in the market without personal<br />
relations, on the other hand older firms will<br />
simply have more well-established personal relations<br />
to business partners or public officials<br />
on that they can continue to build.<br />
For heads of firms from a relation-based economy<br />
it is generally much more difficult to establish<br />
and cultivate personal relations with<br />
foreign business partners that are not acquaint-
Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 29<br />
ed with the specifics of relation-based governance<br />
than with business partners from their<br />
own region or country. Domestic firms will<br />
therefore be less likely to use relation-based<br />
governance mechanisms for business transactions<br />
with foreigners than for transactions with<br />
domestic business partners. As firms with<br />
many foreign business partners will get acquainted<br />
with using formal information and<br />
contracting institutions and will have to invest<br />
in their ability to use these institutions, they<br />
will also be more likely to reduce their reliance<br />
on relation-based governance even for transactions<br />
with domestic business partners. In a<br />
transition economy, relation-based governance<br />
will therefore be comparatively less important<br />
for firms that have more business relations<br />
with customers or suppliers from Western<br />
economies. Similar arguments apply to the<br />
comparison of domestically-owned and foreign-owned<br />
firms. Foreign owners and managers<br />
will generally not be familiar with the<br />
specifics of relation-based governance and it<br />
will be much harder for them to establish personal<br />
relationships with executives of local<br />
firms. At the same time, they are familiar with<br />
rule-based governance instruments. They will<br />
therefore have an incentive to extend formal<br />
governance mechanisms to their local subsidiaries<br />
and their transactions with local partners<br />
as well. In transition economies, foreignowned<br />
(in particular Western-owned) firms can<br />
thus be expected to make less use of personal<br />
relationships than domestically owned firms.<br />
Changing institutional environment for<br />
doing business<br />
China today may be viewed as a society that is<br />
in a gradual process of transition from a relation-based<br />
to a more rule-based governance<br />
system (LI 2004; LI/PARK/LI 2004).<br />
The (traditional) role of personal<br />
relationships in China<br />
The importance and pervasive use of personal<br />
relationships in daily social and business life in<br />
China has been stressed by numerous observers<br />
and has attracted considerable attention<br />
among researchers from various disciplines<br />
(for a partial overview with a focus on business<br />
economics and sociological economics see<br />
LANGENBERG 2007). While the cultivation of<br />
personal relationships, in some form and to<br />
some extent, exists in every society, its specif-<br />
ic form, guanxi, and its pervasiveness and importance<br />
in daily social and business life are<br />
often considered distinctively Chinese (STAN-<br />
DIFIRD/MARSHALL 2000, 22). Guanxi is cultivated<br />
through the repeated exchange of gifts<br />
and favors, which creates a sense of reciprocal<br />
obligation and indebtedness of the partners<br />
(STANDIFIRD/MARSHALL 2000, 22 f.). Developing<br />
bilateral guanxi to several other persons<br />
that may also develop personal relationships<br />
among each other leads to a guanxi network.<br />
As information about a partner’s opportunistic<br />
behavior with one of his exchange partners<br />
spreads through the whole network, such behavior<br />
can easily result in the offending party<br />
being banished from the network altogether.<br />
Within guanxi networks, the threat of network<br />
expulsion increases the cost of opportunistic<br />
behavior, thus providing an increased assurance<br />
that one’s exchange partner will not act<br />
opportunistically. The flow of information<br />
within guanxi networks is not restricted to information<br />
on members’ conduct for the purpose<br />
of sanctioning opportunistic behavior,<br />
however. There is also a vivid exchange of information<br />
about business opportunities and<br />
about the competence and reliability of potential<br />
business partners. “The exchange of information<br />
favors in guanxi networks is so common<br />
that guanxi is said to act as an ‘information<br />
bridge’” (LANGENBERG 2007, 46). These<br />
benefits do not come for free, however. Establishing<br />
and cultivating guanxi networks takes<br />
time and other resources. Moreover, having to<br />
choose, due to reciprocal obligations, transaction<br />
partners from within one’s personal network<br />
may inhibit potentially profitable transactions<br />
with people outside the network (LAN-<br />
GENBERG 2007).<br />
The importance of guanxi in China is not restricted<br />
to relations between private persons.<br />
Given the paramount role that the state (government<br />
and bureaucracy) continues to play in<br />
the Chinese society and economy, personal relationships<br />
with government and party officials<br />
(political relations) are considered to be of<br />
great significance for citizens’ quality of life<br />
and businesses’ success (see, e.g., LANGENBERG<br />
2007). 5<br />
Reform of the formal institutional<br />
environment in China<br />
Since the beginning of economic reforms in<br />
1978 there have been dramatic changes in the<br />
institutional environment for doing business in
30 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
China. By 2007, the year of the company survey<br />
<strong>und</strong>erlying our empirical analysis, formal<br />
contracting, information, and with some reservations<br />
also, property rights institutions have<br />
been improved considerably. The first Economic<br />
Contract Law passed in 1981 was still<br />
intended largely to regularize relations between<br />
state-owned enterprises. As economic<br />
reforms gradually led to a great expansion in<br />
the number and importance of non-state enterprises<br />
the role of contract law shifted towards<br />
governing the interactions between independent<br />
economic agents. The overall scope of<br />
contract laws was gradually broadened by<br />
passing specific contract laws and amending<br />
the Economic Contract Law. In 1999, the different<br />
contract laws were replaced by a new<br />
unified contract law that gave broad range to<br />
freedom of contract and provided a uniform legal<br />
framework for economic contracts by individuals<br />
and enterprises alike, regardless of<br />
ownership and nationality (for details see<br />
CLARKE/MURRELL/WHITING 2008). During the<br />
reform, the importance of courts for the resolution<br />
of disputes over contracts increased substantially.<br />
Despite their many remaining deficiencies<br />
courts are now playing a significant<br />
role in dispute resolution (CLARKE/ MUR-<br />
RELL/WHITING 2008), and in comparison with<br />
other developing and developed countries, the<br />
ability of Chinese courts to solve disputes over<br />
simple and clearly written contracts has been<br />
rated quite favorably (in 2007). 6<br />
Like contract law, many of the public information<br />
institutions that are of great importance in<br />
modern market economies were virtually nonexistent<br />
when the reform process began. By<br />
2007, China has made substantial progress in<br />
reforming or introducing some of these information<br />
institutions – though much remains to<br />
be done. An important example are accounting<br />
standards. In the early stages of the reform<br />
process, several different sets of accounting<br />
rules applying to firms with different ownership<br />
structures and from different industries<br />
were introduced. Generally, these rules deviated<br />
substantially from international accounting<br />
standards. The new Accounting Standards for<br />
Business Enterprises that came into force in<br />
2007 are, by contrast, broadly in line with international<br />
accounting standards but they are<br />
mandatory, for now, only for listed companies.<br />
Despite some convergence with international<br />
standards, the practical application of China’s<br />
accounting principles is still a complex and<br />
opaque process (for additional information see<br />
World Bank 2009). A second example relates to<br />
credit information. In the early 2000s the People’s<br />
Bank of China established a rapidly expanding<br />
Corporate Credit Information Database<br />
that contains information on companies’<br />
bank and non-bank credit relationships (see<br />
JENTZSCH 2008). In 2006, it contained information<br />
on about eleven million enterprises of<br />
which about five million had a credit relationship.<br />
Later the system was extended to include<br />
credit information on individuals. 7 As these examples<br />
illustrate, access to business information<br />
has expanded substantially during the reform<br />
period. Several important reform steps<br />
have been taken only rather recently, however,<br />
and there is still a long way to go before public<br />
information institutions in China reach Western<br />
standards.<br />
Compared to the progress made in improving<br />
formal contracting and information institutions,<br />
reform progress in formal property rights<br />
institutions has been (even) more limited. Only<br />
in 2007, after several years of considerable<br />
controversy and delay, a unified Property Law<br />
was passed. This law introduces and defines<br />
the concept of property rights in a unified way<br />
covering state property, collective property as<br />
well as private property. It defines the rights<br />
owners have over their property and the obligations<br />
assumed by others in respect of this<br />
property. However, to ensure that the law was<br />
passed, a number of areas, including modalities<br />
of legal redress, have been left vague, limiting<br />
the effectiveness of the protection of private<br />
property rights in practice (OECD 2008, 23 ff.;<br />
MARECHAL/TEKIN/GULIYEVA 2009).<br />
More generally, due to broad decision making<br />
powers of numerous (local and central) government<br />
bodies and courts’ inability to effectively<br />
constrain (arbitrary) government action<br />
China’s current legal system is largely unable<br />
to provide secure property rights. A main reason<br />
for courts’ inability to effectively enforce<br />
laws and constrain governments is their political<br />
and financial dependence on local governments.<br />
8 This makes it difficult for courts to decide<br />
against the wishes of local governments,<br />
and allows local governments to influence<br />
courts, or to ignore their decisions, in order to<br />
accommodate the interests of companies with<br />
strong political relationships (CLARKE/MUR-<br />
RELL/WHITING 2008; for examples see LI<br />
2004).
Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 31<br />
In current China, local and central government<br />
officials still hold numerous instruments and<br />
wide discretionary powers to interfere with<br />
business operations and affect business success.<br />
Business operations require licenses, permits<br />
and approvals from various governmental<br />
authorities and are subject to numerous business<br />
laws and regulations. The requirements<br />
for obtaining licenses and permits as well as<br />
the terms and interpretations of business regulations<br />
often lack transparency. They can differ<br />
substantially across provinces, districts and<br />
even towns and are subject to frequent<br />
changes. Business success is also affected by<br />
officials’ decisions on the allocation of landuse<br />
rights and of other scarce resources, or by<br />
their decisions on subsidies, favorable tax<br />
treatments and government procurement contracts.<br />
Against this backgro<strong>und</strong> personal relations<br />
with public officials can help smooth<br />
business operations and reduce the risk of expropriation<br />
by the politically powerful.<br />
Changing institutional business<br />
environment in the PRD<br />
As a consequence of the substantial influence<br />
that local and regional politicians have on<br />
business relevant policies and on the enforcement<br />
of laws and contracts, the quality of the<br />
legal system and of formal market institutions<br />
can differ considerably across Chinese provinces.<br />
Our empirical analysis is restricted to<br />
firms located in the Pearl River Delta in the<br />
province of Guangdong. Therefore, the quality<br />
of the institutional environment of Guangdong<br />
is of particular interest to our analysis. Guangdong<br />
has been a pioneer region of the Chinese<br />
economic reforms over the last three decades.<br />
Since the beginning of reforms the business<br />
and investment environment in Guangdong<br />
has been more developed and more business<br />
friendly than in many other Chinese provinces.<br />
This has recently been confirmed by a World<br />
Bank report (World Bank 2008) that compared<br />
the business and investment environments of<br />
30 major cities in China (from all Chinese<br />
provinces, with the exception of Tibet). Four<br />
indicators of a business-friendly environment<br />
were compared: the ease of starting a business,<br />
of registering property, of getting credit, and of<br />
enforcing contracts. Guangzhou, the capital of<br />
Guangdong, ranked among the top three cities<br />
for all four indicators and it even ranked first<br />
for contract enforcement. Legal and formal<br />
market institutions are thus generally more developed<br />
in Guangdong (and in the PRD in par-<br />
ticular), than in most other Chinese provinces.<br />
Still, as compared to advanced Western countries<br />
(or to neighboring Hong Kong) formal legal<br />
and market institutions in Guangdong are<br />
still clearly deficient and certainly much less<br />
favorable to a rule-based governance of individual<br />
business operations.<br />
It is worth mentioning that the comparatively<br />
advanced institutional reform process in<br />
Guangdong has gone hand in hand with an<br />
expansion and internationalization of (private)<br />
economic activity that is outstanding even for<br />
Chinese standards. Guangdong had the highest<br />
GDP (2,621 bio. RMB) of all Chinese provinces<br />
and the growth rate (15 %) was also among<br />
the highest in China in 2006 (NBSC 2007). In<br />
the same year, the number of state-owned and<br />
non-state-owned industrial enterprises with annual<br />
revenues of over 5 mio. RMB was about<br />
37,500, the second largest number of all Chinese<br />
provinces, and these companies’ gross industrial<br />
output and industrial value added were<br />
higher than the corresponding figures in all<br />
other provinces. Having the second highest<br />
openness index 9 , Guangdong’s economy was<br />
also more strongly integrated into the international<br />
markets than all other Chinese provinces,<br />
with the exception of Shanghai.<br />
For an institutional and economic environment<br />
such as that of Guangdong, or the PRD, the institutional<br />
approach suggests that personal relations<br />
with business partners and with public<br />
officials are still playing an important role for<br />
many firms’ business operations. However,<br />
with continuously improved formal institutions<br />
and with increasing scale and complexity in<br />
business operations on site, certain firms may<br />
already begin to reduce their dependence on<br />
personal relations and to increasingly rely on<br />
formal institutions for governing their business<br />
operations.<br />
Empirical analysis<br />
The PRD Company Survey 2007 on which our<br />
empirical analysis is based was addressed to<br />
executives of electronics companies in the<br />
PRD. 10 As the economically dominant region<br />
within Guangdong province with its comparatively<br />
advanced institutional reform process<br />
and its vivid private enterprise sector, the PRD<br />
constitutes a suitable research region for our<br />
research purpose. The focus on a single indus-
32 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
try helps to reduce industry-level firm heterogeneity<br />
and allows our analysis to focus on<br />
those firm characteristics that are, according to<br />
the theoretical considerations, likely to affect<br />
firms’ decisions on the use of relation-based or<br />
rule-based governance instruments. The electronics<br />
industry was selected due to its substantial<br />
importance for the regional economy in<br />
the PRD. The gross output of the electronics<br />
industry’s enterprises (state-owned enterprises<br />
and non-state-owned enterprises with annual<br />
business revenues of at least 5 mio. RMB)<br />
amounted to 41 % of all industries in 2006<br />
(GPBS 2007). Moreover, the electronics industry<br />
is a very dynamic industry characterized by<br />
short product life-cycles, quick product-related<br />
process modifications, and large research and<br />
development expenditures (TUAN/NG, 1995).<br />
In combination with the high intensity of global<br />
competition within the industry, these features<br />
force companies to continuously optimize<br />
the governance of their business operations.<br />
For our survey a total of 400 electronics companies<br />
were randomly selected from the comprehensive<br />
company catalogue Guangdong<br />
Electronics 2007. Overall 222 of these companies<br />
completed and returned the questionnaire.<br />
Our empirical analysis is based on the responses<br />
to a subset of the questions of these questionnaires.<br />
In the following we first present our<br />
results on the general role of personal relationships<br />
for doing business in the PRD. We then<br />
turn to the results on the importance of personal<br />
relationships (relative to other more formal<br />
and impersonal alternatives) for three critical<br />
business functions, namely for getting into<br />
contact with customers and with suppliers and<br />
for obtaining short-term finance. Finally, we<br />
present evidence on how the importance of<br />
personal relationships for individual firms<br />
varies with firm characteristics such as age,<br />
ownership structure, size and growth performance.<br />
Role of personal relationships<br />
for doing business in general<br />
Within the questionnaire two questions relate<br />
to the general importance of personal relationships<br />
for companies’ business operations in the<br />
PRD, with the first one considering personal<br />
relationships in general and the second one focusing<br />
on political relations. As to the importance<br />
of personal relationships in general, executives<br />
were asked to use a five-level Likert<br />
scale to assess the importance of six specified<br />
reasons for their firms’ decisions to fulfill some<br />
business tasks in the PRD via personal networks:<br />
to “substitute for missing laws and regulations”<br />
(SubMLaw), to “respond quickly to<br />
customer demands” (ResCus), to “increase<br />
company’s operational flexibility” (IncFlex),<br />
to “reduce risks and uncertainties” (RedRisk),<br />
to get “access to business-related information”<br />
(AccInfo), and to “solve business disputes”<br />
(SolDis). In total, about two thirds of respondents<br />
consider responding quickly to customer<br />
demands as a very important or important reason<br />
for their company to fulfill some tasks via<br />
personal relationships, whereas only about a<br />
quarter of them do so for substituting missing<br />
laws/regulations, or for solving business disputes<br />
(Tab.1). The shares of respondents considering<br />
the other three reasons as very important<br />
or important are at intermediate levels. 11<br />
Of the 212 executives who answered this question,<br />
170 executives (about 80 %) considered at<br />
least one reason as very important or important<br />
for their company to fulfill some tasks in PRD<br />
Tab. 1: Importance of reasons for using personal relationships – company distribution<br />
SubMLaw ResCus IncFlex RedRisk AccInfo SolDis<br />
1 very important 24 (13.3) 76 (37.4) 56 (29.3) 40 (21.1) 49 (25.5) 19 (10.4)<br />
2 important 24 (13.3) 60 (29.6) 42 (22.0) 39 (20.5) 28 (14.6) 26 (14.2)<br />
3 of normal<br />
importance 41 (22.8) 38 (18.7) 54 (28.3) 62 (32.6) 62 (32.3) 53 (29.0)<br />
4 of little<br />
importance 26 (14.4) 9 (4.4) 14 (7.3) 17 (9.0) 14 (7.3) 35 (19.1)<br />
5 not important 65 (36.1) 20 (9.9) 25 (13.1) 32 (16.8) 39 (20.3) 50 (27.3)<br />
Total 180 (100) 203 (100) 191 (100) 190 (100) 192 (100) 183 (100)<br />
Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />
Source: own survey
Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 33<br />
via personal relations (not documented in Tab.<br />
1). This suggests that personal relations are, for<br />
one reason or another, playing an important<br />
role for most companies in the PRD. It is less<br />
clear, however, how this relates to the weakness<br />
of formal legal and market institutions in<br />
current China. The two most important reasons<br />
for using personal relations, improving the<br />
ability to quickly respond to customer needs<br />
and increasing companies’ operational flexibility<br />
– the executives’ assessments of the importance<br />
of these two reasons are highly correlated<br />
across firms (Spearman correlation coefficient<br />
of almost 0.6) –, are essentially performance<br />
objectives and relation-based<br />
governance instruments may be advantageous<br />
for achieving these objectives even if formal<br />
institutions were well developed. And the one<br />
reason that explicitly refers to weak formal institutions,<br />
namely using personal relations as a<br />
“substitute for missing laws and regulations”<br />
has been considered important or very important<br />
by a minority (25 %) of respondents only.<br />
This seems to suggest that most companies in<br />
PRD do not see the deficiencies in the institutional<br />
environment but general transactions<br />
costs advantages of relation-based governance<br />
as the main reason for their use of personal relations.<br />
12<br />
Given the fact that public officials in China still<br />
have ample opportunities to directly or indirectly<br />
interfere with business operations and<br />
affect business success, companies may not only<br />
consider personal relationships with private<br />
economic agents important for doing business<br />
in the PRD but also personal relationships with<br />
public officials (political relations). Executives<br />
were therefore asked to assess the importance<br />
of political relations for carrying out five business<br />
“activities” 13 : “getting permissions for<br />
production/investment” (GetPermProd), “get-<br />
ting export/import concessions or licenses”<br />
(GetExImCon), getting “access to buildings<br />
and/or land” (AccBuild), getting “access to<br />
materials and resources” (AccRes), getting<br />
“access to financial support from government”<br />
(AccGovSup). Of the 212 companies that have<br />
answered the question, 144 companies (about<br />
68 %) considered political relations very important<br />
or important for at least one of the “activities”<br />
considered (Tab. 2). While more than<br />
half (54 %) of all respondents considered personal<br />
relationships with public officials very<br />
important or important for companies in PRD<br />
to get permissions for production and investment,<br />
only about 27 % and 31 % of them considered<br />
political relations important or very important<br />
for getting access to materials and resources<br />
and to financial support from<br />
government, respectively. The shares for the<br />
other two alternatives take intermediate values.<br />
These results suggest that political relationships<br />
are still important for companies to get<br />
access to ‘production factors’ that are crucial<br />
for companies’ operations and are still <strong>und</strong>er<br />
the control of government.<br />
An analysis of the pair-wise correlations between<br />
the assessments of the alternatives from<br />
the preceding two questions reveals that those<br />
executives that considered political relations<br />
more important (than other executives) also<br />
tended to consider “missing laws and regulations”<br />
as a more important reason for using<br />
personal relations in general. This may be taken<br />
as an indication that firms tend to consider<br />
the importance of political relations a consequence<br />
of weak formal institutions.<br />
The role of personal relationships for critical<br />
business functions<br />
Getting into contact with customers: It has<br />
been argued that in relation-based economies<br />
Tab. 2: Importance of political relations – company distribution<br />
GetPermProd GetExImCon AccBuild AccRes AccGovSup<br />
1 very important 82 (40.0) 51 (26.3) 44 (22.5) 35 (18.0) 36 (18.7)<br />
2 important 30 (14.6) 28 (14.4) 33 (16.8) 18 (9.3) 24 (12.4)<br />
3 of normal importance 36 (17.6) 47 (24.2) 39 (19.9) 48 (24.7) 39 (20.2)<br />
4 of little importance 16 (7.8) 20 (10.3) 25 (12.8) 27 (13.9) 27 (14.0)<br />
5 not important 41 (20.0) 48 (24.7) 55 (28.1) 66 (34.0) 67 (34.7)<br />
Total 205 (100) 194 (100) 196 (100) 194 (100) 193 (100)<br />
Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />
Source: own survey
34 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
personal relations are playing an important role<br />
in selecting business partners, while other impersonal<br />
alternatives of searching for and<br />
screening (potential) business partners are becoming<br />
more important as formal information<br />
and contracting institutions are getting more<br />
effective. In order to investigate the relative<br />
importance of relation-based governance<br />
mechanisms for companies to find new customers,<br />
we asked the executives to assess the<br />
importance of four different channels for getting<br />
into contact with their customers. (We also<br />
asked them to indicate if their companies<br />
did no use the respective channel at all.) Two of<br />
the four channels are non-relation-based,<br />
namely “bidding competitions”, and “active<br />
searching (e.g., exhibitions, internet, sales<br />
agents)”, while the other two are relationbased,<br />
using “business contacts (e.g., recommendation<br />
from business partners)” or “private<br />
contacts (e.g., recommendation from family<br />
members and friends)”.<br />
The results (Tab. 3) paint a mixed picture of the<br />
(relative) importance of personal relations for<br />
getting into contact with customers. While one<br />
formal channel “bidding competition” was the<br />
least frequently used channel among the companies<br />
in the PRD, the other formal channel “active<br />
searching” was the most frequently used<br />
one with only 10 % of companies not using this<br />
channel at all. The share of executives assessing<br />
“active searching” as very important or important<br />
(65 %) is also the highest one among the<br />
four channels considered. Interestingly, an almost<br />
equal share of executives (61 %) considered<br />
“business contacts”, very important or important.<br />
In contrast, only about a third of respondents<br />
assigned the same importance levels<br />
to the other two channels, private contacts and<br />
bidding competition, respectively. 14<br />
Overall, these results suggest that for a majority<br />
of firms in the PRD personal relations, in<br />
particular existing business contacts, still play<br />
an important role for searching for and screening<br />
new customers. However, despite remaining<br />
deficiencies in the formal institutional environment,<br />
most firms do not exclusively rely<br />
on relation-based channels to get into contact<br />
with customers but make important use of<br />
more formal, impersonal instruments for<br />
searching new customers as well.<br />
Part of an explanation for the substantial importance<br />
of impersonal (formal) instruments<br />
for getting into contact with new customers<br />
may be the importance of foreign customers<br />
(exports) for many electronics companies in<br />
the PRD. Personal relations may be expected to<br />
be of much less importance for these customers.<br />
On average, firms in our sample sold<br />
roughly half of their products (in value terms)<br />
to customers in mainland China and slightly<br />
less than a quarter of products to “advanced<br />
countries” (North America, Western Europe,<br />
Australasia and Japan). We expect that the two<br />
relation-based contacting channels tend to be<br />
more important for companies with higher<br />
shares of product sales in the mainland China.<br />
To test this supposition, we calculated the pairwise<br />
Spearman correlations between the executives’<br />
assessment of the importance of the two<br />
relation-based channels of contacting customers<br />
on the one hand and their firms’ shares<br />
of sales in mainland China on the other hand.<br />
The results confirm our supposition. With respect<br />
to the share of sales in mainland China,<br />
Tab. 3: Importance of channels used to get into contact with customers – company distribution<br />
Bidding Active Business Private<br />
competition searching contacts contacts<br />
1 very important 38 (17.4) 96 (43.6) 67 (30.5) 38 (17.3)<br />
2 important 26 (11.9) 48 (21.8) 67 (30.5) 36 (16.4)<br />
3 of normal importance 27 (12.4) 38 (17.3) 41 (18.6) 49 (22.3)<br />
4 of little importance 13 (6.0) 11 (5.0) 10 (4.6) 25 (11.4)<br />
5 not important 29 (13.3) 5 (2.3) 9 (4.1) 21 (9.6)<br />
Not used 85 (39.0) 22 (10.0) 26 (11.8) 51 (23.2)<br />
Total 218 (100) 220 (100) 220 (100) 220 (100)<br />
Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />
Source: own survey
Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 35<br />
both correlation coefficients are negative –<br />
though only the one for private contacts is statistically<br />
significant – suggesting that the higher<br />
the share of sales realized in mainland China,<br />
the more important the two relation-based<br />
channels for contacting customers.<br />
Getting into contact with suppliers: Similar arguments<br />
also apply to companies’ search for<br />
potent and reliable suppliers. Therefore the<br />
questionnaire also contained a question on the<br />
importance of different channels for getting into<br />
contact with suppliers. The same four channels<br />
as in the case of customers were considered<br />
and the same five-level Likert scale was<br />
applied. The responses are generally quite similar<br />
to those obtained for the case of customers<br />
(Tab. 4). 15 “Bidding competition” turns out to<br />
be the least frequently used channel, while “active<br />
searching” is the most frequently used one.<br />
As to the importance of the four channels considered,<br />
the responses suggest that “active<br />
searching” is the most important channel for<br />
getting into contact with suppliers (with about<br />
70 % of respondents considering this channel<br />
as very important or important), followed by<br />
“business contacts” (about 56 %). “Private<br />
contacts” and “bidding competition” are considered<br />
the least important channels.<br />
As for the case of customers, we expect the two<br />
relation-based channels of getting into contact<br />
with suppliers to be more important for companies<br />
sourcing a greater share of inputs from<br />
Chinese suppliers. On average, companies<br />
source about 73 % of their inputs from mainland<br />
Chinese but only 8 % from the “advanced<br />
countries”. To test this supposition, we calculated<br />
the pair-wise Spearman correlations.<br />
Contrary to our supposition, none of the correlation<br />
was fo<strong>und</strong> to be statistically significant.<br />
One possible explanation for this is that there is<br />
too little variation between firms with respect<br />
to the locations of their suppliers (73 % from<br />
mainland China). Differences between firms in<br />
the importance of the two relation-based channels<br />
for getting into contact with suppliers thus<br />
have to be attributed to differences in other<br />
firm characteristics.<br />
Financing: For relation-based economies in<br />
transition such as current China (or PRD) we<br />
expect personal relations to also play an important<br />
role for companies’ efforts to secure adequate<br />
finance and, in particular, for their ability<br />
to obtain short-term finance. In order to investigate<br />
this issue, executives were asked to<br />
assess the accessibility of six different sources<br />
for meeting their firms’ short-term financial<br />
needs: “Chinese banks”, “HK banks”, “foreign<br />
banks”, “affiliated companies/business partners”,<br />
“customers”, and “family members and<br />
friends”. The last three sourcing alternatives<br />
may be considered relation-based. A five-level<br />
Likert scale was applied, with “1” indicating<br />
“very easily accessible” and “5” “not accessible”.<br />
According to the executives’ responses<br />
(Tab. 5), only about 26 % of companies never<br />
obtained short-term finance from a Chinese<br />
bank, while 44.8 % and 45 % never obtained<br />
short-term finance from “family members and<br />
friends” and from “affiliated companies”, respectively.<br />
About 37 % never did so from “customers”.<br />
Generally, to obtain short-term finance<br />
is not an easy task for most companies.<br />
After all, only about 29% considered it easy or<br />
very easy to obtain short-term finance from a<br />
Chinese bank. For the other (potential) sources<br />
Tab. 4: Importance of channels used to get into contact with suppliers – company distribution<br />
Bidding Active Business Private<br />
competition searching contacts contacts<br />
1 very important 34 (15.7) 93 (42.7) 57 (26.2) 24 (11.1)<br />
2 important 21 (9.7) 58 (26.6) 64 (29.4) 34 (15.7)<br />
3 of normal importance 27 (12.4) 35 (16.1) 52 (23.9) 52 (24.0)<br />
4 of little importance 15 (6.9) 8 (3.7) 7 (3.2) 30 (13.8)<br />
5 not important 37 (17.1) 7 (3.2) 6 (2.8) 23 (10.6)<br />
Not used 83 (38.3) 17 (7.8) 32 (14.7) 54 (24.9)<br />
Total 217 (100) 218 (100) 218 (100) 217 (100)<br />
Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />
Source: own survey
36 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 5: Short-time accessibility of finance by source – company distribution<br />
CNBank HKBank ForBank AffComPart Customer FamFrd<br />
1 very easily<br />
accessible 36 (17.1) 16 (7.6) 5 (2.4) 10 (4.7) 17 (8.1) 15 (7.1)<br />
2 easily accessible 25 (11.9) 22 (10.4) 13 (6.2) 15 (7.1) 29 (13.7) 20 (9.5)<br />
3 normal accessible 36 (17.1) 12 (5.7) 11 (5.2) 38 (18.0) 40 (19.0) 33 (15.7)<br />
4 little accessible 28 (13.3) 8 (3.8) 10 (4.7) 21 (10.0) 25 (11.9) 22 (10.5)<br />
5 not accessible 31 (14.7) 48 (22.8) 54 (25.6) 32 (15.2) 21 (10.0) 26 (12.4)<br />
Not used 55 (26.1) 105 (49.8) 118 (55.9) 95 (45.0) 79 (37.4) 94 (44.8)<br />
Total 211 (100) 211 (100) 211 (100) 211 (100) 211 (100) 210 (100)<br />
Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />
Source: own survey<br />
this number is even lower. To obtain short-term<br />
finance from family and friends was easy or<br />
very easy for only about 17 % of the companies.<br />
The corresponding numbers for customers<br />
and affiliated companies are 22 % and<br />
12 % respectively. 16<br />
The result that many PRD companies face substantial<br />
difficulties when trying to obtain shortterm<br />
finance from Chinese or even foreign<br />
banks should not be surprising, given the deficiencies<br />
in, e.g., accounting and credit information<br />
institutions. It is not generally true,<br />
however that it is easier for firms in the PRD,<br />
and therefore more widespread, to obtain shortterm<br />
finance by using personal relationships<br />
(either with family members, affiliated companies<br />
or customers) to. In particular, only slightly<br />
more than half of all firms ever obtained<br />
short-term finance from family members or<br />
friends and only about one out of six of these<br />
firms considered it (very) easy to obtain finance<br />
from this source. In the following section<br />
we will see, however, that there are significant<br />
differences between different “types” of<br />
firms with respect to their assessment of relation-based<br />
finance.<br />
Firm characteristics and personal<br />
relationships for doing business<br />
We expect that different “types” of firms may<br />
differ systematically in their use of relationbased<br />
versus rule-based instruments for governing<br />
their business operations. More specifically,<br />
larger firms or faster growing firms and<br />
foreign-owned firms in China should tend to<br />
make less use of relation-based governance<br />
than smaller, stagnant and Chinese-owned<br />
firms. We also expect younger, less estab-<br />
lished, firms to rely more on personal relations<br />
than older firms for getting into contact with<br />
new customers or suppliers or obtaining shortterm<br />
finance. This should be true in particular<br />
for private relationships with family members<br />
and friends. We therefore look into the empirical<br />
relation between the executives’ assessment<br />
of the importance of personal relationships (as<br />
reflected by their answers to the questions discussed<br />
above) on the one hand and their firms’<br />
age, ownership structure, size, and growth performance<br />
on the other hand.<br />
Firm characteristics and personal relationships<br />
for doing business in general: In order to<br />
investigate the role of firm characteristics for<br />
the importance of personal relations, we first<br />
analyze the pair-wise correlations between<br />
firm characteristics and executives’ responses<br />
to the questions on the general role of personal<br />
relationships for doing business in the PRD<br />
and on the importance of political relations, respectively<br />
(cf. Tab. 1, 2). The firm characteristics<br />
considered are defined as follows: (1) company<br />
age (Age) is equal to the difference between<br />
the survey year (2007) and the fo<strong>und</strong>ing<br />
year of a company (plus 1); (2) ownership<br />
(ForeignOwn) is an ordinal variable ranging<br />
from 0 to 3 and referring to Chinese-owned enterprise,<br />
Chinese-foreign cooperative joint<br />
venture, Chinese-foreign equity joint venture<br />
and wholly foreign-owned enterprise, respectively;<br />
(3) a first size variable (Employ) is<br />
equal to the average number of total employees<br />
during the year before the survey; (4) a second<br />
size variable (Sales) is an ordinal variable<br />
ranging from 0 to 5, with values corresponding<br />
to different levels of sales in 2006, defined by<br />
the following intervals in million RMB (0, 1),
Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 37<br />
Tab. 6: Relation between firm characteristics and the importance of reasons for relation-based<br />
governance – Spearman correlations<br />
Age ForeignOwn Employ Sales GrowSales<br />
SubMLaw -0.024 (179) -0.065 (177) 0.078 (177) 0.020 (175) -0.186 (172)<br />
ResCus 0.117* (202) 0.123** (198) 0.142** (197) 0.057 (197) -0.023 (192)<br />
IncFlex 0.048 (189) 0.080 (187) 0.094* (187) 0.041 (185) -0.050 (184)<br />
RedRisk 0.129*(188) 0.108* (187) 0.074 (186) 0.072 (184) -0.058 (182)<br />
AccInfo 0.062 (191) 0.176*** (189) 0.123** (186) 0.098* (187) -0.061 (183)<br />
SolDis 0.022 (181) 0.156** (180) 0.109* (180) 0.085 (177) 0.008 (176)<br />
Notes: Numbers in parentheses refer to numbers of corresponding observations.<br />
***/**/* refer to the 1%/5%/10% significance level in two-tailed (Age) or one-tailed significance tests.<br />
Source: own survey<br />
[1, 5), [5, 10), [10, 50), [50, 100), and [100, ∞);<br />
(5) growth performance is measured by an ordinal<br />
variable (GrowSales) with four classes (0<br />
to 3) for the average annual growth rates since<br />
2002, where classes are defined as (-∞, 0%),<br />
[0%, 2%), [2%, 10%), [10%, ∞) (see also the<br />
appendix).<br />
The Spearman correlations between firm characteristics<br />
and the importance of the six reasons<br />
for using personal relations are reported in<br />
Tab. 6. For the age variable five of the six correlations<br />
are positive, though only two of them<br />
(“responding quickly to customer demands”<br />
and “reducing risks and uncertainties”) are statistically<br />
significant. 17 Still, the predominantly<br />
positive correlations could be considered as<br />
(weak) support for the view that personal relations<br />
are generally more important for younger<br />
firms, e.g. because it is relatively more difficult<br />
and costly for them to use formal institutions<br />
and public reputation mechanisms to govern<br />
their business relations.<br />
As to the ownership structure, correlation results<br />
give strong support for our hypothesis<br />
that greater foreign participation in company<br />
ownership is associated with a lower general<br />
importance of personal relationships for that<br />
company. This effect may (partially) be attributed<br />
to the fact that foreign owners will generally<br />
be more (less) acquainted with rule-based<br />
governance (relation-based governance). Legal<br />
and cultural norms of the foreign owners’ home<br />
country may aggravate reservations against the<br />
use of informal, relational institutions.<br />
Correlation results for the size variables, particularly<br />
those for the employment variable,<br />
give support to our supposition that personal<br />
relations tend to be less important for larger<br />
firms. All correlations with respect to “Employ”<br />
are positive and four out of six are statistically<br />
significantly so. Correlations with respect<br />
to the other variable used to proxy firm<br />
size, “Sales”, are also uniformly positive,<br />
though only one of them is significant. As to<br />
firm growth there is no supportive evidence for<br />
our supposition of a positive relation between a<br />
company’s growth performance and the general<br />
relevance of personal relationships, however.<br />
Almost all relevant correlations are negative<br />
(though generally quite small), suggesting that<br />
a better growth performance of firms is, if anything,<br />
associated with a greater importance of<br />
(the various reasons for using) personal relationships.<br />
A possible explanation is that fast<br />
growing firms may have to mobilize all their<br />
resources, including their personal networks,<br />
and use all available formal and informal governance<br />
instruments to support their expansion.<br />
Turning next to the importance of political relations<br />
for doing business in the PRD, there<br />
seem to be (almost) no associations of this with<br />
the different firm characteristics (see Tab. 7).<br />
Given the severe deficiencies of the institutional<br />
environment in China with respect to the<br />
protection of private property rights against expropriation<br />
by government and the ample opportunities<br />
that public officials have to interfere<br />
with firms’ business operations and success,<br />
political relations seem to be of similar<br />
importance for all types of companies. 18<br />
Firm characteristics and the role of personal<br />
relationships for critical business functions:<br />
We, finally, investigate the association between<br />
firm characteristics and the importance of personal<br />
relations for contacting new customers
38 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 7: Relation between firm characteristics and the importance of political relations – Spearman<br />
correlations<br />
Age ForeignOwn Employ Sales GrowSales<br />
GetPermProd -0.053 (203) 0.003 (200) 0.100* (199) 0.061 (198) 0.064 (193)<br />
GetExImCon -0.115 (192) -0.144 (191) -0.101 (190) -0.071 (188) -0.029 (184)<br />
AccBuild -0.165 (194)* -0.046 (192) -0.085 (192) -0.119 (190) -0.028 (186)<br />
AccRes -0.094 (192) -0.039 (190) -0.001 (191) 0.147** (189) 0.066 (185)<br />
AccGovSup -0.036 (191) 0.029 (190) 0.082 (191) 0.099* (188) 0.054 (185)<br />
Notes: Numbers in parentheses refer to the numbers of corresponding observations.<br />
***/**/* refer to the 1%/5%/10% significance level in two-tailed (Age) or one-tailed significance tests.<br />
Source: own survey<br />
and new suppliers as well as for obtaining<br />
short-term finance. We expect each of the firm<br />
characteristics – firm age, firm size, growth<br />
performance and foreign ownership – to be<br />
negatively related to the importance of relation-based<br />
governance instruments. (Note that<br />
contrary to the case of the general role of personal<br />
relationships for doing business we do<br />
expect a negative effect of age on the importance<br />
of personal relations here. Due to our importance<br />
scale, “1” being very important, this<br />
implies that we are expecting positive correlation<br />
coefficients). In order to test these suppositions,<br />
we calculated pair-wise Spearman correlations<br />
between the different firm characteristics<br />
and the importance of relation-based<br />
governance for getting into contact with customers<br />
and with suppliers and for obtaining<br />
short-term finance.<br />
The results (Tab. 8) suggest that firm age, in<br />
particular, is playing an important role for<br />
firms’ decisions to use relation-based governance<br />
in the business context considered here.<br />
Most age-related correlations are significantly<br />
positive, suggesting that younger firms tend to<br />
consider relation-based channels more important<br />
(more easily accessible) than older firms<br />
for getting into contact with their customers<br />
and suppliers (for obtaining short-term finance).<br />
Moreover, the correlations between<br />
firm age and the importance of private contacts<br />
to get into contact with customers and suppliers<br />
are (slightly) larger than the correlations<br />
with respect to business contacts. This suggests<br />
that as firms get older the importance of private<br />
(e.g., family) relations tends to decline faster<br />
than that of relations to business partners in<br />
general. This may reflect the simple fact that<br />
younger firms, can build on a limited network<br />
of business contacts but a relatively larger pool<br />
of private contacts, whereas the business network<br />
tends to increase as firms get older. This<br />
effect seems to be even substantially stronger<br />
for firm size.<br />
For both measures of firm size the correlations<br />
with the importance of private relations for<br />
making contacts with both customers and suppliers<br />
are positive and statistically highly significant,<br />
while correlations with the importance<br />
of business contacts are insignificant.<br />
This suggests that larger firms tend to rely<br />
more on personal contacts but no less on business<br />
contacts for screening new customers and<br />
suppliers than smaller firms. When firms are<br />
small, existing private contacts may be sufficient<br />
for supporting their business operations.<br />
However, as firms grow and their operations<br />
become more numerous and manifold, existing<br />
private contacts may become an insufficient<br />
basis for expanding the business. Contrary to<br />
our expectations, there seems to be no systematic<br />
effect of firm size on the importance or accessibility<br />
of relation-based sources of shortterm<br />
finance. In addition, as above (and possibly<br />
also for the same reasons) we do not find<br />
any support of our supposition of a negative association<br />
between firms’ growth performance<br />
and the importance of personal relations.<br />
As to foreign ownership, there is, again contrary<br />
to our expectations, no statistically significant<br />
effect of the ownership structure on the<br />
importance of private or business relations for<br />
contacting new customers and suppliers. At<br />
least the sign of the correlations suggests, however,<br />
that private contacts but not business contacts<br />
might be slightly less important for firms<br />
with foreign ownership participation. This may<br />
be interpreted as an indication of a substitutive<br />
relation between private and business contacts.
Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 39<br />
Tab. 8: Relation between firm characteristics and the importance of relation-based instruments<br />
for critical business functions – Spearman correlations<br />
Age ForeignOwn Employ Sales GrowSales<br />
Contacting customers<br />
Business contacts 0.104* (217) -0.072 (216) 0.001 (211) 0.063 (211) -0.117 (205)<br />
Private contacts 0.203*** (217) 0.084 (216) 0.223***(211) 0.188*** (211) -0.012 (205)<br />
Contacting suppliers<br />
Business contacts 0.161*** (216) -0.049 (214) 0.032 (209) -0.041 (210) -0.020 (202)<br />
Private contacts 0.185*** (215) 0.037 (213) 0.158** (209) 0.158** (210) 0.024 (204)<br />
Short-term financing<br />
AffComPart -0.043 (209) 0.040 (207) -0.085 (203) 0.060 (203) 0.054 (197)<br />
Customer 0.020 (209) 0.113* (207) -0.023 (203) 0.032 (203) -0.009 (197)<br />
FamFrd 0.124** (208) 0.234*** (206) 0.090 (202) 0.087 (202) 0.051 (196)<br />
Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the numbers of corresponding observations. Coding as in Table 3, Table 4,<br />
and Table 5, respectively; with “not used = 6”. For further explanations see appendix.<br />
***/**/* refer to the 1%/5%/10% significance level in one-tailed significance tests.<br />
Source: own survey<br />
The limited number of private contacts on site<br />
may induce foreign-owned firms to more<br />
strongly rely on existing business contacts for<br />
extending their business to new customers and<br />
suppliers. With respect to financing, the effect<br />
of the ownership pattern is more clear-cut and<br />
consistent with our supposition. All three relation-based<br />
sources are less important for shortterm<br />
financing for firms with stronger foreign<br />
ownership interests and the coefficients regarding<br />
“customers” and “family and friends” are<br />
statistically significant or even highly significant.<br />
In summary, for most firms personal relationships<br />
with business partners and with political<br />
officials seem to be of substantial importance<br />
for doing business in the PRD in general. For<br />
several critical business activities – getting into<br />
contact with new customers and suppliers<br />
and accessing short-term finance – relationbased<br />
mechanisms and sources are not generally<br />
more important than more formal or impersonal<br />
ones, however. Finally, there is some,<br />
though generally rather weak, evidence that<br />
firm characteristics, such as company age, size<br />
and foreign ownership are, as expected, negatively<br />
associated with firms’ reliance on personal<br />
relationships for at least some of the<br />
business functions considered. In contrast, no<br />
systematic (negative) relation was fo<strong>und</strong> in<br />
general between firms’ growth performance<br />
and the importance of personal relationships.<br />
Conclusions<br />
China today may be viewed as a society that is<br />
in a gradual process of transition from an informal<br />
and relation-based to a more formal<br />
and rule-based governance system. At the<br />
macro-level of the institutional environment<br />
there have been, over the last decades, remarkable<br />
improvements of the formal contracting,<br />
information and (with some reservations)<br />
property rights institutions. This is true, in particular,<br />
for the province of Guangdong, which<br />
has been a pioneer region of economic and institutional<br />
reform in China, and for the PRD,<br />
Guangdong’s core economic region. Even<br />
there, however, the quality of many formal legal<br />
and market institutions is still far from<br />
what it is in most advanced economies.<br />
In light of the gradual character of the reform<br />
process and the remaining deficiencies in the<br />
institutional environment, theoretical considerations<br />
suggest that informal institutions and<br />
personal relations with private business partners<br />
and with political officials can be expected<br />
to be still of considerable importance for<br />
the firm-level governance of business operations<br />
in the PRD, in general. Given the continuing<br />
improvements of formal institutions at<br />
the macro-level and an increasing scale and<br />
scope of firms’ business operations, firms’<br />
marginal costs of developing personal relations<br />
will increase and their benefits will decrease.<br />
As a consequence, firms operating in<br />
China will tend to gradually reduce their re-
40 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
liance on informal relation-based governance<br />
and make increased use of rule-based governance<br />
instruments, such as formal contracting<br />
and public information institutions, instead.<br />
Not all firms will have equally strong incentives<br />
to move from relation-based to more formal<br />
governance mechanism, however. Rather,<br />
we expect the incentives to reduce the reliance<br />
on personal relations to be stronger, in particular,<br />
for older, larger and faster growing firms as<br />
well as for firms with more international business<br />
contacts (international suppliers or customers)<br />
or with larger foreign ownership interests.<br />
These suppositions were confronted with firmlevel<br />
data obtained from a survey of 222 companies<br />
of the electronics industry operating in<br />
the PRD. Though most of the empirical results<br />
seem to be broadly in line with the theoretically<br />
fo<strong>und</strong>ed suppositions, the empirical evidence<br />
is generally rather weak. This weakness<br />
may be partially attributed to a small sample<br />
size and the limited number of relevant variables<br />
we could construct from the available<br />
database. The paper should thus be taken only<br />
as a first, exploratory attempt to obtain (empirical)<br />
evidence on the relation between firm<br />
characteristics and the firm-level importance of<br />
relation-based governance during China’s institutional<br />
reform process. Future research may<br />
build and improve upon the current study by<br />
employing a larger and richer database on an<br />
issue that is of considerable importance to the<br />
future economic development of China and<br />
other transition economies.<br />
Acknowlegement<br />
Liu would like to thank the German Research Fo<strong>und</strong>ation<br />
(DFG) for its financial support of the cooperative<br />
projects “Informal Dynamics of Agile Firm Organization<br />
in the Greater Pearl River Delta” and “Regional<br />
Agility and Upgrading in Hong Kong and the PRD”<br />
(Priority Program 1233: Megacities - Megachallenge:<br />
Informal Dynamics of Global Change).<br />
Notes<br />
1 The Pearl River Delta (PRD) comprises nine municipalities<br />
of the Chinese Province of Guangdong:<br />
Dongguan, Foshan, Guangzhou, Huizhou, Jiangmen,<br />
Shenzhen, Zhaoqing, Zhongshan, and Zhuhai.<br />
2 <strong>Institut</strong>ions that improve the availability and quality<br />
of information on economic agents’ past conduct<br />
and their ability to perform include accounting and<br />
auditing rules, credit rating and credit reporting institutions<br />
and land and liens registries. As these institutions<br />
also impact the cost of designing, managing<br />
and enforcing contractual agreements there are<br />
important interdependencies between information<br />
institutions and contracting institutions.<br />
3 In relation-based governance systems agreements<br />
are, therefore, mostly enforced by second-party enforcement<br />
mechanisms: each party to an ongoing relationship<br />
is deterred from behaving opportunistically<br />
and from breaching the (implicit) agreement<br />
by the other parties’ threat to retaliate and/or to terminate<br />
the relationship. Sometimes agreements and<br />
information about business partners’ performance<br />
will be made partially explicit and verifiable to<br />
third-parties to allow for third-party enforcement,<br />
which may take one of two forms. In relation-based<br />
third party enforcement, the deterrent to breach an<br />
agreement is strengthened by the threat that the miscreant<br />
will be barred from future business not only<br />
with the particular partner on which he acted opportunistically<br />
but with a whole group of (potential)<br />
business partners. This threat may be further buttressed<br />
by social ostracism if the group fosters social<br />
ties among its business members (DIXIT 2004, 27 f.).<br />
The second form is third party enforcement by the<br />
state, which will not generally be impartial in relation-based<br />
systems, however. Frequently, in case of<br />
conflict, the contracting parties’ personal relations<br />
with politicians or state officials will determine the<br />
enforcement outcome or the ex-post bargaining<br />
power of the parties (LI 2003, 657).<br />
4 The basic formal institutions of a society generally<br />
also tend to be quite persistent and their change<br />
mostly incremental. Occasionally, however, windows<br />
of opportunity arise, in which formal institutions<br />
can change very fast and in large discrete steps<br />
(NORTH 1990, 89 ff.).<br />
5 Political relations can be a ‘lubricant’ for a wide variety<br />
of private or business-related activities: e.g.,<br />
obtaining driver’s licenses, getting access to medical<br />
treatment or to universities, gaining favorable<br />
verdicts in lawsuits, obtaining the permits required<br />
for all kind of business operations, getting access to<br />
scarce resources.<br />
6 In terms of the ease or difficulty of enforcing a simple<br />
commercial contract, China ranked 20th of 178<br />
economies in the World Bank’s report “Doing Business<br />
2008” (World Bank 2007). Criteria used to determine<br />
the ranking are the time, the cost and the<br />
number of procedures involved from the moment a<br />
plaintiff files the lawsuit until actual payment in a<br />
specific, well defined commercial dispute.<br />
7 The scope, accessibility and quality of credit information<br />
available through either public or private<br />
credit registries and their coverage are central criteria<br />
in the World Bank’s ease of ‘getting credit’-index.<br />
For this index, China ranked 84th of 178<br />
economies in 2007 (World Bank 2007).<br />
8 The power to appoint and to dismiss courts’ leadership<br />
rests with government or party organizations at
Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 41<br />
the same administrative level. Local governments<br />
also control court finances, material supplies, and<br />
welfare benefits for court officials (CLARKE/MUR-<br />
RELL/WHITING 2008, 395). Other reasons for the<br />
lack of efficient law enforcement are the widespread<br />
corruption and the generally low level of legal training<br />
and competence of judges (TREBIL-COCK/LENG<br />
2006, 1554).<br />
9 The openness index is defined as the value of external<br />
trade (exports plus imports) over GDP. Its value<br />
for Guangdong was 1.604 in 2006 (second only to<br />
that of Shanghai with a value of 1.750).<br />
10 The survey was carried out <strong>und</strong>er the cooperative<br />
project “Informal Dynamics of Agile Firm Organization<br />
in the GPRD” financially supported by the<br />
Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG). The survey<br />
was conducted by our local partner, Prof. Li and<br />
his team from the Geography and Planning School<br />
at the Sun Yat-Sen University in Guangdong.<br />
11 This ranking of the importance of the different reasons<br />
is confirmed by two-tailed pair-wise Wilcoxon<br />
Signed-Rank Tests (WSRTs). According to these<br />
tests ResCus (IncFlex) is the most (second most) important<br />
reason for companies in the PRD to use personal<br />
relationships for business, while SolDis and<br />
SubMLaw are the two least important ones.<br />
12 In a related study among executives of Hong Kong<br />
based companies operating in the PRD (BICKEN-<br />
BACH/LIU 2010) institutional deficiencies were considered<br />
important or very important by a substantially<br />
larger share of executives (55 %). A possible<br />
explanation is that executives from Hong Kong are<br />
more familiar with the working of well developed<br />
formal rules and are therefore also more aware of<br />
the substitutive role of formal and informal governance<br />
instruments.<br />
13 In this question executives were asked to evaluate<br />
the importance of political relations in PRD in general,<br />
not just for their company. We chose to formulate<br />
this question in a less personal way as it may be<br />
considered highly sensitive by executives (due to a<br />
possible association of political relations with<br />
bribery and corruption). We still think that executives’<br />
responses are largely determined by their own<br />
experience, however.<br />
14 Two-tailed WSRTs, considering only firms that<br />
make use of the respective channels, support this<br />
ranking: “active searching” and “business contacts”<br />
are the 1st and 2nd most important channels, respectively.<br />
The other two channels are significantly<br />
less important (with no statistically significant difference<br />
between the two).<br />
15 Correlation analyses between the responses to the<br />
questions on customer contacts and on supplier contacts<br />
show that executives that emphasize the importance<br />
of private contacts (business contacts) for<br />
contacting suppliers also tend to do so for contacting<br />
customers.<br />
16 Pair-wise WSRTs (considering only firms that make<br />
use of the respective sources) indicate that the differences<br />
between Chinese banks, family and friends<br />
and customers are not statistically significant. However,<br />
these three sources are statistically significantly<br />
easier to access than either HK banks, affiliated<br />
companies, or foreign banks.<br />
17 With respect to firm age, two-tailed significance<br />
tests were used, as it is unclear a priori whether we<br />
should expect a positive or a negative relation between<br />
firm age and the general importance of personal<br />
relationships for doing business. With respect<br />
to the other firm characteristics one-tailed significance<br />
tests were used as we have formulated unambiguous<br />
hypotheses about the expected sign of the<br />
relations.<br />
18 It may be worth noting, however, that all correlations<br />
with the age variable are negative though not<br />
significant (with one exception). This may be considered<br />
weak evidence for older firms tending to rely<br />
more on political relations than younger firms.<br />
This is different from the case of personal relations<br />
in general (Tab. 6), where age tends to have the opposite<br />
effect.<br />
Appendix<br />
Basic information on firm characteristics<br />
Age (Age): The youngest companies in the sample were<br />
fo<strong>und</strong>ed in the year of survey (2007), the oldest one in<br />
1952. Half of the companies were fo<strong>und</strong>ed after 2000,<br />
thus having less than 8 years of experience in doing<br />
business in the PRD. On average, companies interviewed<br />
have about 10 years of business experience in<br />
the PRD.<br />
Ownership Structure (ForeignOwn): About 57 % of<br />
companies are Chinese-owned companies, of which<br />
about 94 % are private companies (the rest being stateowned<br />
or collectively-owned). Among the companies<br />
with foreign ownership participation (about 43 % of all<br />
companies), 80 % were wholly foreign owned, 17 %<br />
were Chinese-foreign equity joint ventures, and 3 %<br />
Chinese-foreign cooperative joint ventures.<br />
Employment (Employ): The mean value is 742 employees.<br />
The variation of the variable is substantial ranging<br />
from 2 employees in the smallest firm to 30,000 employees<br />
in the largest (standard deviation 2,867). In<br />
about 85 % of companies the number of employees is<br />
below the average. The first, second and third quantile<br />
of the number of total employees of companies interviewed<br />
is 51, 150, and 500 persons, respectively.<br />
Sales (Sales): The greatest share of firms (30 %) falls in<br />
the category with sales between 10 million and 50 million<br />
RMB. The shares of companies realizing sales in<br />
the categories (-∞, 1), [1, 5), [5, 10), [50, 100), and<br />
[100, ∞) are about 9 %, 23 %, 16 %, 9 %, and 13 %, respectively.<br />
Growth Performance (GrowSales): The shares of firms<br />
in categories 0 to 3 are 3.4 %, 17.9 %, 48.3 % and 30.4<br />
%, respectively. This implies that for almost 80% of<br />
firms sales increase by an average rate of more than 2 %<br />
per year.
42 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
References<br />
ACEMOGLU, D./JOHNSON. S. (2005): Unb<strong>und</strong>ling institutions.<br />
In: Journal of Political Economy, (113)5, 949-<br />
995.<br />
BARDHAN, P. (2005): <strong>Institut</strong>ions matter, but which<br />
ones? In: Economics of Transition, (13)3, 499-532.<br />
BICKENBACH, F./LIU, W.-H. (2010): On the role of personal<br />
relationships for doing business in the Greater<br />
Pearl River Delta, China. In: China Economic Journal,<br />
(3)3, 281-306.<br />
CLARKE, D./MURRELL, P./WHITING, S. (2008): The role<br />
of law in China’s economic development. In: Brandt,<br />
L./Rawski, T.G. (Eds.): China’s Great Economic Transformation.<br />
Cambridge/UK, New York, 375-428.<br />
DAVIES, H./LEUNG, T.K.P./LUK, S.T.K./WONG, Y. (1995):<br />
The benefits of ‘guanxi’: The value of relationships in<br />
developing the Chinese market. In: Industrial Management<br />
Marketing, (24), 207-214.<br />
DIXIT, A.K. (2004): Lawlessness and economics. Alternative<br />
modes of governance. Princeton/ New Jersey.<br />
GPBS (Guangdong Provincial Bureau of Statistics)(2007):<br />
Guangdong statistical yearbook 2007. Beijing.<br />
GREIF, A. (2005): Commitment, coercion, and markets.<br />
The nature and dynamics of institutions supporting exchange.<br />
In: Ménard, C./Shirley, M.M. (Eds.): Handbook<br />
of New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics. Dordrecht, 727-786.<br />
JENTZSCH, N. (2008): An economic analysis of China’s<br />
credit information system. In: China Economic Review,<br />
(19), 537-550.<br />
LANGENBERG, E.A. (2007): Guanxi and business strategy.<br />
Theory and implications for multinational companies.<br />
Heidelberg.<br />
LI, S. (2004). Why is property rights protection lacking<br />
in China? An institutional explanation. In: California<br />
Management Review, (46)3, 100-115.<br />
LI, S./PARK, S.H./LI, S. (2004): The Great Leap Forward.<br />
The transition from relation-based governance to<br />
rule-based governance. In: Organizational Dynamics,<br />
(33)1, 63-78.<br />
LI, J.S. (2003): Relation-based versus rule-based governance.<br />
An explanation of the East Asian miracle and<br />
Asian crisis. In: Review of International Economics,<br />
(11) 4, 651-673.<br />
LUO, Y. (1997): Guanxi and performance of foreign-invested<br />
enterprises in China. An empirical inquiry. In:<br />
Management International Review, (37), 51-71.<br />
LUO, Y. (2007): Guanxi and business. Singapore. (2nd<br />
ed.)<br />
MARECHAL, V./TEKIN, P./GULIYEVA, H. (2009): China’s<br />
new property rights law - an important step towards improving<br />
access to credit for small and medium enterprises.<br />
Internet: http://www.doingbusiness.org/documents/casestudies/2009/DB09_Reforms_China.pdf,<br />
20.9. 2010.<br />
NBSC (National Bureau of Statistics of China)(2007):<br />
China statistical yearbook 2007. Beijing.<br />
NORTH, D. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change and<br />
economic performance. Cambridge.<br />
OECD (2008): OECD investment policy reviews - China<br />
2008. Encouraging responsible business conduct.<br />
Paris.<br />
PARK, S.H./LUO, Y. (2001): Guanxi and organizational<br />
dynamics. Organizational networking in Chinese firms.<br />
In: Strategic Management Journal, (22)5, 455-477.<br />
STANDIFIRT, S.S./MARSHALL, R.S. (2000): The transaction<br />
cost advantage of Guanxi-based business practices.<br />
In: Journal of World Economics, (35)1, 21-42.<br />
TREBILCOCK, M./LENG, J. (2006): The role of formal<br />
contract law and enforcement in economic development.<br />
In: Virginia Law Review, (92), 1517-1580.<br />
TUAN, C./Ng, L.N.Y. (1995): Evolution of Hong Kong’s<br />
electronics industry <strong>und</strong>er a passive industrial policy.<br />
In: Managerial and Decision Economics, (16)5, 509-<br />
523.<br />
WILLIAMSON, O.E. (1996): The mechanisms of governance.<br />
New York.<br />
World Bank (2007): Doing business 2008. Washington<br />
DC. Internet: http://www.doingbusiness.org/documents/<br />
FullReport/2008/DB08_Full_Report.pdf , 20.9. 2010.<br />
World Bank (2008): Doing Business in China 2008.<br />
Washington DC. Internet: http://www.doingbusiness.<br />
org/subnational/exploreeconomies/China.aspx.<br />
World Bank (2009): Report on the observance of standards<br />
and codes (ROSC). Accounting and auditing. People’s<br />
Republic of China. Internet: http://www.worldbank.org/ifa/rosc_aa_chn.pdf,<br />
20.9. 2010. (The World<br />
Bank. Financial Management – Central Operational<br />
Services Unit, East Asia and Pacific Region)<br />
XIN, K.R./PEARCE, J.L. (1996): Guanxi. Connections as<br />
substitutes for formal institutional support. In: Academy<br />
of Management Journal, (39)6, 1641-1658.<br />
ZENGER, T./LAZZARINI, S./POPPO, L. (2002): Informal<br />
and formal organization in New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics.<br />
In: Ingram, P./Silverman, B. (Eds.): Advances in<br />
strategic management. The new institutionalism in<br />
strategic management. Oxford, 275-303.
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S.43-57<br />
Markus Keck/Hans-Georg Bohle, Bonn/Wolfgang-Peter Zingel, Heidelberg<br />
Dealing with insecurity<br />
Informal business relations and risk governance among food wholesalers in Dhaka,<br />
Bangladesh<br />
Abstract: The article investigates <strong>und</strong>erlying social mechanisms that contribute to the remarkable<br />
resilience of Dhaka’s food system with a special focus on wholesalers and their informal business<br />
networks. A relational approach to the subject matter is elaborated that <strong>und</strong>erstands informality as<br />
a specific governance mode of business relations that is coined by horizontal power relations, and<br />
by the implicit codification, endogenous imposition, and personalized implementation of procedural<br />
rules. Empirical evidence is presented from recent fieldwork with rice and fish wholesalers<br />
that suggests that informality, in the form of trustworthy relations and social capital, has the potential<br />
to foster the traders’ adaptive capacities and thus not only their individual business performance,<br />
but also the overall robustness of the urban food system.<br />
Keywords: informality, embeddedness, wholesaling, food system, Bangladesh<br />
Introduction<br />
Since the 1970s, Dhaka exhibits unprecedented<br />
rates of population growth and spatial expansion<br />
that have let it become one of the largest<br />
cities worldwide (UN 2008). At a current<br />
growth rate of 3.5 % (World Bank 2007), its<br />
population increases by an estimated number<br />
of 450.000 people every year. Such a rapid urbanization<br />
process not only challenges governmental<br />
authorities –SIDDIQUI et al. (2000) attested<br />
the capital of Bangladesh already at the<br />
end of the last century a severe and extensive<br />
‘governance crisis’ (cf. also ISLAM 2005). It also<br />
brings up the question of how urban supply<br />
and distribution systems currently work <strong>und</strong>er<br />
such conditions. In the following this question<br />
is examined by taking the food system of Dhaka<br />
as a case. Food systems are conceived as a<br />
set of activities ranging from production, processing<br />
and packaging, over distribution and<br />
retailing, to final consumption (ERICKSON<br />
2008, 236). Despite their overwhelming importance,<br />
distribution systems, particularly in the<br />
urban context, are least <strong>und</strong>erstood (BOHLE et<br />
al. 2009, 9). As GUYER (1987) has rightly noted,<br />
urban food supply and distribution is usually<br />
seen as a routine function in all kinds of so-<br />
cieties and taken for granted most of the time<br />
by those not directly involved. More often than<br />
not, it is <strong>und</strong>er conditions of food crises that urban<br />
food supply suddenly becomes “a public<br />
issue which can blaze on the political agenda<br />
with suddenness, urgency, and often ferocity”<br />
(loc.cit. 1). While the persistence of famines in<br />
the era of global change has been discussed<br />
from manifold and diverse vantage points (DE-<br />
VEREUX 2007), the question of what social<br />
mechanisms exactly shape the resilience of urban<br />
food systems during non-famine times<br />
widely lacks empirical evidence in the literature.<br />
Our study concentrates on the entry points of<br />
food into the city, i.e. on the wholesale markets<br />
as the major distributional nodes from which<br />
food flows into various channels of the urban<br />
food system. Empirical data are presented on<br />
rice and fish wholesalers’ risk adaptation activities,<br />
with a special focus on informality. It is assumed<br />
that it is the continuous effort of food<br />
traders in general and their constant investment<br />
in informal business relations in particular that<br />
determines the food system’s overall resilience<br />
to a large extent.
44 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
The food system of Dhaka and its<br />
robustness<br />
In 1951, Dhaka had a population of 336,000<br />
(BBS 1951 after ISLAM 2005, 13); today there<br />
are roughly 14.2 million (ISLAM 2010, 6): 42<br />
times more inhabitants than before! While the<br />
first figure refers to the area of the Dhaka City<br />
Corporation (DCC) with an extension of 145<br />
km 2 , the latter number refers to Dhaka Metropolitan<br />
Development Planning Area (DMDP)<br />
with a size of 1,528 km 2 . For all those people<br />
who are involved in the megacity’s food system,<br />
the rapid urbanization means a challenge<br />
in economic, financial and logistical ways.<br />
Surprisingly, however, Dhaka’s food supply<br />
system has been remarkably resilient over the<br />
past 40 years.<br />
In most of South Asia, rice is the major staple<br />
of the people, regardless of their economic,<br />
social, or ethnic backgro<strong>und</strong>. On average, the<br />
citizens of Dhaka meet their caloric demand to<br />
65 % by cereals. With an average intake of 378<br />
g per head and day, cereals (almost exclusively<br />
rice) are the most important basic food items<br />
for Dhaka’s and Bangladesh’s population (cf.<br />
BBS 2007). Bangladesh’s rice granaries are located<br />
in north-western and northern regions of<br />
the country (KECK et al. 2008, 29). Rice is<br />
grown mostly on small farms of less than 2.5<br />
acres (1 ha). Up to three harvests are possible<br />
per year, i.e. aman, boro and aus (AHMED<br />
2001, 2; DOROSH et al. 2004, 14). In the fiscal<br />
year 2006/07 55 % of the total rice production<br />
stemmed from the boro season, whereas aus<br />
lost its importance and plays only a marginal<br />
role now with hardly 6 % (FPMU 2009, 1).<br />
Bangladesh has been able to more than triple<br />
rice (paddy) production since independence in<br />
1971. Domestic production rose from 14.9 million<br />
tons in 1971 to 43.1 million tons in 2007<br />
and to a record harvest of 46.9 million tons in<br />
2008 (here and in the following “tons” refer to<br />
metric tons). This success was possible only<br />
because yields increased from 1,602 kg/ha in<br />
1971 to 3,995 kg/ha in 2008. Today, Bangladesh<br />
holds the fourth position among the<br />
world’s rice producing countries. But despite<br />
all impressive production increases, Bangladesh<br />
is still not in a position to feed its population.<br />
More than 3 million tons foodgrains had<br />
to be imported in 2007: 2.4 million tons wheat,<br />
0.6 million tons (milled) rice and 0.2 million<br />
tons maize (FAOSTAT 2010). In 2008 rice imports<br />
counted for well over 1 million tons<br />
(FAO 2009b, 25).<br />
Bangladesh’s market liberalization of the<br />
1990s coincided with India’s removal of export<br />
restrictions. India’s rice exports increased dramatically<br />
from 0.9 million tons in 1994 to 4.9<br />
million tons in 1995. India started dominating<br />
the rice imports of her neighbour, thus replacing<br />
Thailand as the major source of rice imports<br />
to Bangladesh (DOROSH/MURSHID 2004,<br />
109). One has to bear in mind, however, that<br />
India had been exporting rice to Bangladesh also<br />
before, although illegally and unrecorded.<br />
The long and winding border was never effectively<br />
controlled and whenever prices differed<br />
in the two neighbouring countries, large quantities<br />
would be smuggled across. But also after<br />
India started to liberalise its foreign trade, she<br />
continued to look at her consumers first. In<br />
times of high world market prices, India restricts<br />
her exports rather than allow her domestic<br />
prices to rise. As a consequence, India’s rice<br />
exports were reduced from 5 million tons in<br />
2007 (FAO 2008, 32) to 3.57 million tons in<br />
2008 (FAO 2009a, 29) at a time when<br />
Bangladesh needed to import. In 2007, floods<br />
and the cyclone Sidr brought devastation and<br />
much of the paddy crop was destroyed. Consequently,<br />
the country had to import large quantities<br />
of grain just when world market prices<br />
started to rise to unprecedented heights. In late<br />
2007, the price of the major rice exporters<br />
showed a pronounced increase with a peak in<br />
mid-2008. The price of high quality Thai rice<br />
almost quadrupled (!) within a period of one<br />
year. From August 2004 until November 2006<br />
it had risen from 250 US$/t to 300 US$/t, while<br />
afterwards it jumped up to more than 1,000<br />
US$/t in mid-2008. From the end of 2008 onwards<br />
prices fell and remained at a high level<br />
of aro<strong>und</strong> 600 US$/t (www.indexm<strong>und</strong>i.com,<br />
20.8.2009). The situation in Dhaka followed<br />
this general trend. Here, prices of low quality<br />
(coarse) rice, that is mainly consumed by low<br />
income groups, more than doubled in the mentioned<br />
period, i.e. from 16.50 Bangladesh Taka<br />
(BDT) in January 2006 to 35.00 BDT in December<br />
2008. Since the beginning of the year<br />
2009 prices have come down again to a rate of<br />
20.00 BDT to 25.00 BDT (ZINGEL et al. 2011,<br />
305; according to data provided by the Ministry<br />
of Agriculture, Department of Agricultural<br />
Marketing, Government of the People’s Republic<br />
of Bangladesh).<br />
Although this hike of world rice prices caused<br />
severe distortions of Bangladesh’s food security<br />
situation (for a discussion of its impact on
Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 45<br />
Dhaka’s urban poor see ZINGEL et al. 2011),<br />
there has always been enough food in the city<br />
to secure at least a minimum supply for the urban<br />
population. Without wanting to downplay<br />
the “silent violence” (cf. WATTS 1983) that was<br />
caused by the food price hike, it must be mentioned<br />
that dispite Dhaka’s rapid growth,<br />
countrywide floods, the devastating cyclone<br />
Sidr, the global food price hikes, and political<br />
upheaval, the food supply and distribution system<br />
as a whole remained remarkably stable.<br />
What are the social mechanisms that made this<br />
system so resilient? To answer the question,<br />
our analysis will focus on food wholesalers<br />
and their informal business networks. Before<br />
moving to the empirical part of this paper, the<br />
term of informality has to be clarifyed.<br />
Informality – a relational approach<br />
Although HART (1973) and his colleagues of<br />
the International Labour Organization’s employment<br />
missions (ILO 1972) were quite<br />
positive about the informal sector – noting its<br />
efficiency, creativity, and resilience – in subsequent<br />
years, the concept was widely interpreted<br />
in negative terms. Scholars from many<br />
disciplinary backgro<strong>und</strong>s referred to informality<br />
in such a way and assessed it predominantly<br />
in terms of demanding, dirty, and dangerous<br />
labour conditions, unregistered and partly illegal<br />
small-scale ‘survival economies’, or marginal<br />
residential areas (for the informal sector<br />
debate see CHEN 2006). From this vantage<br />
point, megacities are often described as global<br />
risk areas (KRAAS 2008), that are menaced by<br />
environmental degradation, capacity overload<br />
of public distribution systems, marginalization,<br />
social exclusion, and prevailing poverty<br />
that all together add to the vulnerability of<br />
large segments of cities worldwide (KRAAS/<br />
MERTINS 2008). But, despite these sad truths,<br />
informality in today’s megacities also bears<br />
the inherent potential for adaptive and efficient<br />
governance modes and, thus, opportunities for<br />
future development that should not be overseen<br />
(KRAAS/NITSCHKE 2006). In this article, it<br />
is the positive aspects of informality that are<br />
aimed to be put back on the agenda of the current<br />
debate.<br />
In order to elaborate a relational approach to<br />
informality, we draw back on the work of<br />
NORTH (1990) on formal and informal institutions.<br />
According to NORTH (loc.cit. 3), institu-<br />
tions are <strong>und</strong>erstood as all kinds of “humanly<br />
devised constraints that shape human interaction”,<br />
whereas constraints encompass obligations<br />
and restrictions, but also rights and privileges<br />
(SCOTT 2008, 50). Since human beings<br />
live in an uncertain world, they device institutions<br />
to bring about some security and to minimize<br />
related transaction costs (DE SOYSA/ JÜT-<br />
TING 2007, 31). While formal institutions are<br />
codified political, juridical, and economic rules<br />
that are outlined in constitutions, laws, ordinances,<br />
and all kinds of legal contracts, that are<br />
usually enforced by official entities such as<br />
parlaments, courts, bureaucrats, and other legal<br />
persons (NORTH 1990, 55 ff.), informal institutions<br />
are basically <strong>und</strong>erstood as uncodified social<br />
norms that are reproduced largely through<br />
self-enforcing mechanisms of mutual agreement.<br />
As such they comprise customs and<br />
habits, obligations and social entitlements, and<br />
all kinds of other deontic rules (loc.cit. 43 ff.).<br />
According to NORTH (loc.cit. 55), the difference<br />
between formal and informal institutions<br />
is a matter of degree; both kinds of rules together<br />
span a continuum. Consequently, social<br />
realities seldomly fit into either the one or the<br />
other category. Instead, organizations as the<br />
players of the game are rather embedded in an<br />
“institutional matrix” that comprise both formal<br />
and informal institutions at the same time<br />
(loc.cit.1990; 2005). Despite these regulative<br />
and normative aspects of formal and informal<br />
institutions (cf. SCOTT 2008), SEARLE (1995)<br />
convincingly addressed the <strong>und</strong>erlying constitutive<br />
element of institutions. Based on collective<br />
intentionality, that is the cognitive property<br />
of human beings to direct their minds in<br />
agreement with each other at specific states of<br />
affairs in the world, people turn brute facts into<br />
institutional facts and thus produce social reality<br />
in accordance to the logical form of “X<br />
counts as Y in C”. For instance, the brute fact<br />
of a handshake (X) in the context of a market<br />
place (C) counts as the closing of a contract<br />
(Y), if both partners of this interaction agree<br />
upon it. As such, all institutional facts, e.g.<br />
money, marriage, business organizations or<br />
governments, do indeed exist only because we<br />
believe them to exist.<br />
This constitutive feature of institutions is most<br />
tricky (ADELSTEIN 2010, 344), especially when<br />
considering informal institutions. Since it is a<br />
matter of social consensus, first of all, different<br />
scales of institutions are to be distinguished,<br />
from mutual agreements between two partners
46 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 1: Continuum of formal and informal relations<br />
Formal-informal<br />
continuum<br />
<strong>Institut</strong>ions reproduced<br />
in social relations<br />
Strong- formal Statutory law and<br />
authority<br />
Weak-formal Market and<br />
delegation<br />
Governance and social interaction<br />
Explicit codification, exogenous imposition, as<br />
well as rigid and depersonalized implementation<br />
of processual rules in hierachical power relations<br />
Rigid and depersonalized implementation<br />
Weak-informal Culture and ethics Implicit codification, endogenous imposition, as<br />
Strong-informal Personal trust and<br />
friendship<br />
Source: LI 2007, 230; ETZOLD et al. 2009, 8<br />
in dyadic relationships over widely accepted<br />
norms of a society to nearly universalistic values<br />
of global humanity. Secondly, institutions<br />
must be perceived as being in permanent flux<br />
and motion, they constantly arise and vanish as<br />
they are the subject of permanent negotiation<br />
in contested political arenas (ETZOLD et al.<br />
2009). Taking into account GIDDENS’ (1984)<br />
theory of structuration and his elaboration on<br />
people’s agency, we can speak of a duality of<br />
institutions that constitutes them as both medium<br />
and outcome of social practices. With these<br />
considerations in mind, we may distinguish<br />
with LI (2007) between formality and informality<br />
as a specific governance mode of social<br />
interaction. Formality refers to procedural<br />
rules that are “explicitly prescribed, exogenously<br />
imposed, and rigidly enforced by vertical<br />
authority powers in a (sic!) universalistic<br />
depersonalized process”, while informality refers<br />
to institutions that are “implicitly assumed,<br />
endogenously embraced, and flexibly enforced<br />
by horizontal peer pressures in a particularistic<br />
personalized process” (loc.cit. 229). By these<br />
criteria, personalized trust, strong social ties,<br />
and affective commitment are strong-informal<br />
elements, while clan control, religion, culture<br />
and ethics are weak-informal. Similarly, law,<br />
state policies, legal ownership, and organizational<br />
hierarchies are strong-formal, while<br />
more or less regularized markets and delegation<br />
are weak-formal (see Tab.1). Such a conceptualization,<br />
thus, allows to apply informality<br />
to both the political and the economic sphere<br />
of society.<br />
With this differentiation, LI (2007) builds a<br />
bridge to the debates on embeddedness (cf.<br />
GRANOVETTER 1973, 1985; UZZI 1996, 1997)<br />
well as flexible and personalized implementation<br />
of processual rules in horizontal power relations<br />
Flexible and personalized implementation<br />
and social capital (cf. COLEMAN 1990; PUTNAM<br />
1993; PORTES 1998; BURT 2001; BOHLE 2005).<br />
With the term of embeddedness, GRANOVETTER<br />
(1990, 98; cited after GLÜCKLER 2001, 214) insists<br />
on the fact that economic action and outcomes<br />
“are affected by actors’ personal<br />
[dyadic] relations, and by the structure of the<br />
overall network of relations”. In this regard he<br />
speaks of relational and structural aspects of<br />
embeddedness. LI (2007, 231 ff.) also follows<br />
this differentiation and distinguishes between<br />
the structure of social relations, expressed as<br />
measures of network diversity and density, as<br />
well as positions of centrality and rank, and the<br />
content of social relations, expressed as measures<br />
of dyadic tie strength and access benefits.<br />
The focus of this article is on the content<br />
of social relations at the scale of dyadic relations<br />
and – more precisely – on personalized<br />
trust as a “mode of commitment [that] results<br />
from strong ties, and also results in relationship<br />
commitment behavior” (loc.cit. 236). By following<br />
GRANOVETTER (1985, 487), informality<br />
is thus approached empirically from the perspective<br />
of “concrete, ongoing systems of social<br />
relations”. In this regard, social capital is<br />
addressed as “an informal access to others’ resources<br />
due to social ties” (LI 2007, 231).<br />
To sum up, informality is a specific governance<br />
mode of social relations in horizontal networks,<br />
most prominently expressed in trustworthy<br />
ties, that comprise institutional<br />
arrangements that are implicitly codified, endogenously<br />
imposed, and dealt with in a flexible,<br />
personalized and thus particularistic manner.<br />
While social ties are the antecedents or<br />
prerequisites of relations, social practices are<br />
the outcome or consequence of institutions. As
Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 47<br />
such, social relations, institutions, and social<br />
practice together appear as an interdependent<br />
trialectic which is the fo<strong>und</strong>ing pillar of the<br />
constant reproduction of social reality.<br />
Informal relations and risk adaptation<br />
of food wholesalers in Dhaka<br />
Food wholesalers in Dhaka<br />
As prerequisite for empirical work, the food<br />
system of Dhaka was analytically subdivided<br />
into three different layers, i.e. (i) the wholesaling<br />
of raw food (wholesale markets; single<br />
wholesale stores), (ii) the retailing of raw food<br />
(kitchen markets; permanent retail shops; supermarkets;<br />
semi-permanent and mobile hawkers),<br />
and (iii) the sale of cooked food (restaurants;<br />
canteens; street food stalls). For the<br />
study of the first layer, in total, 42 rice and fish<br />
wholesalers were consulted by means of qualitative<br />
interviews. In addition, certain questions<br />
were deepened with the help of the participatory<br />
tool of Venn diagrams (KUMAR 2000), that<br />
were <strong>und</strong>ertaken with support of local market<br />
associations. Quantitative measures such as<br />
mappings and a panel survey were used to<br />
broaden the perspective of the study. A standardized<br />
random sample survey was conducted<br />
with 448 wholesalers (206 rice and 242 fish<br />
wholesalers) at 21 wholesale markets (twelve<br />
rice and nine fish markets) to test certain hypotheses.<br />
1<br />
Food wholesalers play a pivotal role within the<br />
megaurban food system of Dhaka. They are<br />
crucial intermediaries between providers and<br />
suppliers on the one hand, and retailers and<br />
consumers on the other. The panel survey<br />
(2009 and 2010) revealed that, at present, raw<br />
food is sold at 87 wholesale markets within the<br />
area of Dhaka City Corporation (DCC) (see<br />
Fig. 1). 2 Out of them, there are 24 rice and 13<br />
fish markets with an estimated total number of<br />
1.700 wholesalers (roughly 900 fish and 800<br />
rice wholesalers) who work in 90 % of the<br />
cases as commission agents by order of rice<br />
millers, pond owners or intermediary suppliers<br />
in rural areas (own survey 2009). Sales<br />
amounts of 3,800 kg rice and 800 kg fish on<br />
average per day, and monthly expenses of<br />
32.000 Bangladesh Taka (BDT) in the case of<br />
rice traders and 63.000 BDT in the case of fish<br />
traders on average are substantial compared to<br />
those of retailers or street food vendors. These<br />
sheer numbers show the traders’ significance<br />
within the urban food system. Nevertheless,<br />
there are great socioeconomic disparities amid<br />
the wholesalers. In terms of business volume,<br />
the top 10 % of Dhaka’s fish merchants sell<br />
39 % of the total turnover, while the bottom<br />
10 % sell only 2 %; respective numbers for rice<br />
traders are 35 % and 2 % (own survey 2010).<br />
Besides few ‘big fishes’ among the wholesalers,<br />
large millers and pond owners in rural<br />
areas and the emerging supermarkets with their<br />
much higher profit margins dominate the food<br />
system.<br />
Urban stress and business risks<br />
Qualitative interviews revealed a variety of insecurities<br />
that the merchants face in Dhaka.<br />
From the traders’ perspective, we can distinguish<br />
between the general stress that is related<br />
to social life in the megacity, and particular<br />
risks that are related to the business of wholesaling<br />
as such. Stress refers to negatively perceived<br />
long-term trends such as the accelerated<br />
population growth and spatial expansion of<br />
Dhaka especially since independence that bestows<br />
on customers and merchants ever increasing<br />
distances and travel times. In order to<br />
keep in step with these developments, wholesalers<br />
establish more and more markets at the<br />
urban fringe. For the merchants, this is a viable<br />
strategy to secure their livelihoods. For the<br />
city, these markets are of vital importance. Despite<br />
Dhaka’s rapid urbanization and a number<br />
of inhabitants that easily exceeds that of most<br />
European states, a sufficient number of markets<br />
guarantees enough food to be brought to<br />
the consumer in an efficient way.<br />
Other types of stress are related to the goverance<br />
of the megacity. The most prominent example<br />
is the bribing of numerous power brokers,<br />
such as patrolling policemen in order to<br />
get access to otherwise restricted roads, bureaucrats<br />
in order to reduce the time waiting in<br />
queues, or criminals that would guarantee market<br />
place security in return. Other examples are<br />
the governmental markets of the city. Wholesalers<br />
need to pay high advance payments in<br />
order to be allowed to appropriate and use<br />
these public places. Actually, these markets<br />
have been established by the municipality for<br />
being leased out to the merchants. However,<br />
more often than not, there are lessees who lease<br />
particular market plots in order to rent them out<br />
to the merchants. As such, the public markets<br />
of Dhaka are severely subject to rent-seeking
48 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Fig. 1: Food wholesale markets in Dhaka City<br />
53 8<br />
56<br />
12<br />
50 8<br />
Shah Ali<br />
51<br />
35<br />
54<br />
>250<br />
55<br />
4<br />
57<br />
10<br />
Adabar<br />
52 9<br />
7<br />
15<br />
58 7<br />
6<br />
153<br />
45<br />
10<br />
46 7<br />
Mirpur<br />
Foodtype<br />
Rice<br />
Fish<br />
Pulses / Edible Oil<br />
Fruits / Vegetables / Wheat<br />
Animals / Meat / Eggs<br />
Daily Turnover in Metric Tons<br />
>250 Tons<br />
>50 - 250 Tons<br />
>1 - 50 Tons<br />
12 Name of Market<br />
45 Number of<br />
Wholesale Stores<br />
Settlements in Dhaka<br />
Metropolitan Area (2003)<br />
0<br />
Water Bodies<br />
Major Roads<br />
Railway<br />
1<br />
2 km<br />
Pallabi<br />
48<br />
14<br />
49<br />
12<br />
44<br />
14<br />
80<br />
23<br />
9<br />
40<br />
47<br />
7<br />
Karful<br />
Mohammadpur<br />
77<br />
8<br />
12<br />
15<br />
84<br />
45<br />
Dhanmondi<br />
15<br />
30<br />
42<br />
20<br />
83<br />
70<br />
16<br />
60<br />
40<br />
65<br />
79<br />
>250<br />
41<br />
5<br />
85<br />
35<br />
81<br />
15<br />
18<br />
11<br />
43<br />
5<br />
60<br />
7<br />
76<br />
20<br />
82<br />
48<br />
78<br />
>250<br />
Hazaribag<br />
Shahbag<br />
8<br />
30<br />
10<br />
14<br />
New Market<br />
100<br />
21 40<br />
11 20<br />
12<br />
8<br />
150<br />
Kamrangir<br />
Char<br />
Buriganga River<br />
Military<br />
Airport<br />
Lalbag<br />
Tejgaon<br />
Draft: M. Keck and S. Raupp<br />
Source: Author's own survey 2008-2010<br />
Cartography: G. Storbeck,<br />
Department of Geography,<br />
University of Bonn<br />
International<br />
Airport<br />
13<br />
63<br />
23<br />
17 100<br />
30<br />
Cantonment<br />
86 5<br />
24<br />
3<br />
61<br />
3<br />
31<br />
17<br />
25<br />
100<br />
19<br />
30<br />
87<br />
30<br />
28<br />
100<br />
33<br />
65<br />
Uttara<br />
Gulshan<br />
Tejgaon I/A<br />
Paltan<br />
32<br />
35<br />
63<br />
4<br />
70<br />
30<br />
66<br />
18<br />
67<br />
4<br />
62<br />
4<br />
69<br />
3<br />
29<br />
30<br />
22<br />
12<br />
5<br />
201<br />
Old Dhaka<br />
Kot- 26<br />
wali >250<br />
5<br />
2<br />
Khilgaon<br />
Kamalapur<br />
Train Station<br />
Motijheel<br />
27<br />
30<br />
Sutrapur<br />
3<br />
20<br />
4<br />
60<br />
59<br />
60<br />
65<br />
5<br />
64<br />
7<br />
68<br />
79<br />
71<br />
8<br />
75<br />
11<br />
Sabujbag<br />
74<br />
34<br />
73<br />
12<br />
34<br />
258<br />
38<br />
100<br />
36<br />
22<br />
2<br />
77<br />
Uttara<br />
Badda<br />
37<br />
>250<br />
35 Jatra-<br />
250 bari<br />
39<br />
35<br />
1<br />
16<br />
72<br />
8
Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 49<br />
1 Azampur Rail Gate Fish Market<br />
2 Sultan Shah Fish Market<br />
3 Tarun Mahmud Shah Fish Market<br />
4 BDR Wholesale Markt<br />
5 Narda Bazar Rice Market<br />
6, 7 Krishi Market<br />
8 New Market<br />
9 Hazi Sayed Hossain Fruits Market<br />
10 Khalil Sarder Krishi Market<br />
11 Nawabganj Rice Market<br />
12 Lalbag Fort Mor Bazar<br />
13 Swarighat Fish Market<br />
14 - 19 Moulavi Bazar<br />
20 Chowk Bazar<br />
21 Begum Bazar<br />
22, 23 Badamtuli / Babubazar<br />
24 Nazira Bazar<br />
25 Sadar Ghat<br />
26 - 28 Shyam Bazar<br />
29 - 33 Kaptan Bazar<br />
34 - 39 Jatrabari<br />
40 - 43 Kochukhet Market<br />
44 Fakirbari Bazar<br />
45 Mirpur 10 Rice Market<br />
46 - 49 Mirpur 11 Kacha Bazar<br />
50 - 52 Mirpur 1 Kacha Bazar<br />
53 Boro Bazar<br />
54 Gabtoli Cattle Market<br />
55 - 57 Dipjol Bazar<br />
58 Mirpur 2 Bazar<br />
59 Notun Bazar<br />
60, 61 Mohakhali Puran Bazar<br />
62 Modda Badda Bazar<br />
63 - 65 Uttor Badda Bazar<br />
66 Uttor Badda Rice Market<br />
67 Merul Badda Fruits Market<br />
68 Merul Badda Fish Market<br />
69 Rampura Bazar<br />
70 Chowdhuripara Rice Market<br />
71 Sipahibag Hotel Bazar<br />
72 Madertek Bazar<br />
73 Mugdapara Boro Bazar<br />
74 Mugdapara Fish Market<br />
75 Khilgaon Railgate Bazar<br />
76 Govt. Hawkers Market Tejgaon<br />
77 West Nakhal Para Bazar<br />
78 - 86 Kawran Bazar<br />
87 Malibag<br />
activities of widely unknown actors who use<br />
their social relations to political elites to capitalise<br />
on the contested public space in Dhaka.<br />
In terms of business risks, the wholesalers<br />
mentioned a range of adverse incidents that can<br />
be further differentiated in risks that (i) are related<br />
to internal affairs of a wholesaling enterprise,<br />
(ii) those that are related to the wholesalers’<br />
suppliers and customers, and (iii) those<br />
that are related to the wider context of the<br />
megacity. Examples of the first case are the replacement<br />
of staff or employees’ accidents. Examples<br />
of the last category comprise the theft<br />
of goods by outsiders, the robbery on the way<br />
to the bank, or the eviction by state authorities.<br />
Inthe following the focus is on the second category<br />
of risks that are related to the merchants’<br />
business relations to their suppliers and customers.<br />
Based on results of qualitative interviews,<br />
in the standardized survey, the traders<br />
were asked to appraise a selected number of<br />
such risks in regard to the frequency of their<br />
occurance, the perceived severity of their impact,<br />
and the time and effort that is necessary to<br />
cope with them. In the survey it was asked for<br />
six particular types of risks, i.e. the default of<br />
credit paybacks by customers, late delivery of<br />
goods, the delivery of already deteriorated<br />
goods, the default of an entire truck load, the<br />
default of the delivery of goods by a supplier<br />
after the wholesaler paid him in advance, and<br />
the closure of the shop for one day due to supply<br />
cuts. In relation to each of these risks, four<br />
related questions were asked. The first question<br />
was: How often did this incident happen in the<br />
course of the last three years?. Answers were<br />
predefined and ranged from never (that equals<br />
a value of 1), over once (2), 2-3 times (3), and<br />
4-5 times (4), to more than 5 times (5). In a second<br />
question, it was asked for the perceived<br />
severity of the risk impact. It was asked: How<br />
do you assess the severity of the impact of<br />
this/these event/s on your business performance?.<br />
Answers ranged from not severe (1) to<br />
extremely severe (4). The third question addressed<br />
the recovery time after the specific<br />
event occured. It was asked: After this/these<br />
event/s, how long did you need to recover from<br />
its negative impact? Similar to the questions<br />
before, answers were pregiven; at most a week<br />
was weighted with 1, a month with 2, several<br />
months with 3, a year with 4, and more than a<br />
year with 5 points. Eventually, it was asked:<br />
After this/these events, how much extra management<br />
effort did you need to overcome the
50 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Fig. 2: Rice and fish wholesalers’ susceptibility to business risks<br />
Severity<br />
3.30<br />
2.80<br />
2.30<br />
B<br />
E<br />
F<br />
F<br />
problem? Answers ranged from no extra effort<br />
(1) to extreme extra effort (4).<br />
The results in Fig. 2 are the mean numbers, for<br />
rice and fish wholesalers individually. While<br />
the severity and frequency of the mentioned<br />
risks are plotted on the x- and y-axis, the recovery<br />
time and managerial effort are expressed<br />
in a combined way as cost of coping,<br />
that is indicated in the diagramme as symbol<br />
sizes. This cost of coping is calculated by summing<br />
the scores of recovery time (1 to 5) by the<br />
scores of managerial effort (1 to 4), thus resulting<br />
in an index with a range from 1 to 9. The<br />
risk appraisal from the perspective of the food<br />
wholesalers generally follows the logic that<br />
more frequent shocks are evaluated as much<br />
less severe (see Fig. 2). Contrary, less frequent<br />
shocks are assessed as being not only much<br />
more severe in their impact, they also involve<br />
much higher costs of coping for the traders. As<br />
such, late delivery of goods is more frequent in<br />
its occurance but perceived as less severe in its<br />
impact than the supply of already deteriorated<br />
goods. As the approximation curves show, fish<br />
business in general involves more frequent and<br />
D<br />
E<br />
1.80<br />
0.70 1.70 2.70<br />
Frequency<br />
3.70 4.70<br />
Source: own survey 2010, own draft<br />
D<br />
B<br />
C<br />
A<br />
C<br />
A<br />
Fish Wholesalers (n=242)<br />
Rice Wholesalers (n=206)<br />
A: Default of credit payback<br />
by customer<br />
B: Default of delivery by<br />
supplier despite advance<br />
payment<br />
C: Late delivery of goods<br />
D: Default of truckload<br />
E: Shop closure for a day<br />
due to supply cuts<br />
F: Delivery of deteriorated<br />
goods<br />
Costs of Coping:<br />
7.05<br />
2.82<br />
more severe risks in comparison to rice business,<br />
a matter that is explained by the different<br />
perishability of both goods.<br />
Nevertheless, four business related risks do not<br />
fit into this general trend. First of all, the risk of<br />
shop closure due to supply cuts equals a frequency<br />
of nearly zero in the case of rice traders.<br />
The reason behind is, that rice traders usually<br />
command godowns that allow rice to be stored<br />
at least for some days. Beside that, the risk of<br />
customers who do not pay back their credits is<br />
evaluated to be not only highly frequent, but also<br />
highly severe in its consequence. In case of<br />
fish wholesalers, the risk that suppliers do not<br />
deliver goods despite the fact that money was<br />
already paid in advance, is also assessed in this<br />
way. The extraordinary positions of these last<br />
three risks in the appraisal are seen as an indication<br />
for the general importance they have for<br />
the everyday business of the merchants. It is argued<br />
that it is especially these financial risks<br />
that make informal trustworthy relationsships<br />
between the traders and their suppliers and customers<br />
so important.
Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 51<br />
Case study: A fish wholesaler<br />
and his business relations<br />
Md. Gilgad Gazi is one of more than 270<br />
wholesalers of Five-Star Fish Market at<br />
Kawran Bazar in the heart of Dhaka City<br />
(market no. 78, Fig. 1). He is in his late 30s<br />
and comes from a small village (gram) not far<br />
from the city of Narail (in Narail district). Mr.<br />
Gazi moved to Dhaka in 1993. He lives together<br />
with his wife and children in a small<br />
appartment in Mohammadpur, some three<br />
kilometers away from his place of work. His<br />
father was a salesman for clothing and taught<br />
him everything he needed to know about how<br />
to manage a store.<br />
Mr. Gazi started his business in 1993 with a<br />
vending stall at Sonali Market (one of the five<br />
compo<strong>und</strong>s of Five-Star Fish Market). He<br />
rented a second stall in 1997, and a third one<br />
in 2001. In 2007, he had the financial resources<br />
to rent three further stalls. Today, he<br />
runs six fish vending sites with a total number<br />
of 20 employees. Each one is run by a manager,<br />
an auctioneer and a weigher. Two helpers<br />
rotate between the single stalls to make shure<br />
that there is always enough fish to be sold<br />
(Venn-diagram of Mr. Gazi in Fig. 3).<br />
From all his employees, Mr. Gazi places one<br />
of his managers (1) first, giving him the highest<br />
score of importance. During the market<br />
hours, this manager is responsible for the<br />
same tasks as the other managers. But afterwards,<br />
he collects the records and earnings of<br />
all other managers for the central book-keeping.<br />
As such, he has decisive control over the<br />
total income of Mr. Gazi’s six vending sites.<br />
The six auctioneers (2) are placed second.<br />
From all other workers, they are most important<br />
due to their responsibility to realize good<br />
sales prices. As he explains, the auctioneers<br />
must be very experienced. They need to know<br />
the customers and their bargaining behavior,<br />
and they need to strategically manage the auctioning<br />
by forcing or reducing the pace. In<br />
third position are the managers of his remaining<br />
five vending sites and his six weighers (3).<br />
He <strong>und</strong>erlines that all of them fulfill important<br />
tasks. Nonetheless, he evaluates them to be of<br />
lower importance compared to the hitherto<br />
mentioned employees. Interestingly, the night<br />
labourers (4), who are not directly employed<br />
by himself but by the market association, are<br />
assessed to be more important and socially<br />
closer to him than his own labourers (5). He<br />
explains this by the fact that the night labourers<br />
bear the responsibility for the unloading of<br />
the trucks and for the correct allocation of his<br />
supplies, a task that they perform independently<br />
at night when his workers are not yet at<br />
the market. The responsibilities of his own<br />
labourers are much less.<br />
After the explanation of the role of his employees,<br />
Mr. Gazi turns to his suppliers. He divides<br />
his 16 suppliers into three groups. Each<br />
group is regarded with different degrees of importance<br />
and placed in different distances to<br />
himself: “There are times, when I deal only<br />
with ten suppliers. But there are also times<br />
when I deal with up to 16 suppliers at the same<br />
time. Ten of my suppliers are very important<br />
for my business. They all deliver fish aro<strong>und</strong><br />
the whole year. The others are far less important.<br />
I know them, but we do business only<br />
from time to time”. In fact, the first (6) and the<br />
second (7) group of suppliers are those whom<br />
Mr. Gazi provides with advance payments<br />
(dadon) that range from 50,000 to 150,000<br />
BDT per year. As return service, they are<br />
bo<strong>und</strong> to deliver a certain amount of fish of a<br />
specific type in regular intervals. Every New<br />
Year, at hal katta, the contracts are anewed.<br />
With four of them (6), very close bonds exisit,<br />
as they stem from Mr. Gazi’s home district<br />
Narail. These four suppliers are those partners<br />
with whom he started his business. To share<br />
the same home district is seen as the f<strong>und</strong>amental<br />
pillar of these relationships. The relations<br />
to the six following suppliers (7) rest on<br />
a long joint business history. In fact, Mr. Gazi<br />
deals with all of them for ten years and more.<br />
These long-lasting business relations and the<br />
shared experience are enough proof for the<br />
good will of each of them. The remaining six<br />
suppliers (8) can be harked back to in times of<br />
need or can be dealt with in case of good offers.<br />
As Mr. Gazi <strong>und</strong>erlines, these suppliers<br />
must be trustworthy as well for fullfilling mutual<br />
agreements. Nonetheless, these six latter<br />
suppliers are not as familiar to him as his other<br />
suppliers are.<br />
Mr. Gazi mentions further that there are approximately<br />
250 customers who come to his<br />
vending sites every day. He divides his stock<br />
of customers into two categories. The first<br />
category (10) consists mainly of retail shop<br />
owners that can be located easily. All actors of<br />
this first category are regular customers. They
52 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Fig. 3: The Venn-diagramme of Mr. Gazi<br />
Source: own draft<br />
Employees<br />
Suppliers<br />
are well known to Mr. Gazi and his employees<br />
and they usually purchase large quantities of<br />
fish. There is usually not much bargaining<br />
with these customers, and most of them get<br />
fish on credit. The second category (11) consists<br />
of all casual customers who are not personally<br />
known to Mr. Gazi and with whom no<br />
social relation exists. For purchasing fish, they<br />
need to participate the auctions. None of them<br />
gets fish on credit.<br />
Beside his employees, his suppliers and his<br />
customers, Mr. Gazi mentions five more actors<br />
or actor groups that are of relevance for<br />
his business performance. The first one is his<br />
The sentimental and instrumental<br />
value of informal relations<br />
Market<br />
Association<br />
Mr. Gazi Scale of Social Proximity: Relevance for Business Performance:<br />
Close – – – – – – – – – – Distant „very low“ – – – – – – – „very high“<br />
The Venn diagramms proved that food wholesalers<br />
in Dhaka are embedded in social networks<br />
linking them to various actors. The<br />
traders maintain ties not only to their suppliers<br />
and customers, but also to other wholesalers, to<br />
banks and local money lenders, to land lords,<br />
local policemen, ward commissioners and municipal<br />
bureaucrats. Regarding the organization<br />
of supply, it was fo<strong>und</strong> that the food traders ba-<br />
5<br />
17<br />
4<br />
Lessor, Land<br />
Owner<br />
8<br />
7 9<br />
6<br />
3 2 1<br />
16<br />
14<br />
15<br />
12<br />
13<br />
10<br />
11<br />
Customers<br />
Business<br />
Partner<br />
Bank,<br />
Moneylender<br />
Government, Dhaka City<br />
Corporation<br />
brother (12), whom he calls his closest business<br />
partner. The second actor is his bank (13)<br />
that he needs to transfer money to his suppliers.<br />
The third actor group is the DCC (14) and<br />
the central government (15), which are relevant<br />
for the trade license and tax that need to<br />
be paid. Furthermore, there is the market association<br />
(9), which runs a credit system. Each<br />
wholesaler usually pays a daily amount of<br />
20.00 BDT into a common pool, which is<br />
available as credit in case of need. The last actors<br />
that Mr. Gazi mentions are the land owners<br />
of the market (17) and his lessor (landlord)<br />
(16)<br />
Source: own interview, 23.2. 2009<br />
sically apply two strategies. On the one hand<br />
they maintain long-standing informally governed<br />
relations to a limited number of suppliers.<br />
On the other hand they maintain relations<br />
to a number of socially distant suppliers<br />
that are governed by formal arrangements.<br />
Even though there are businessmen who pursue<br />
either the first or the second strategy, in<br />
most cases, both are applied at the same time.<br />
Typically, traders are tied to a number of selected<br />
and socially close suppliers from whom<br />
they regularly receive large portions of goods.
Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 53<br />
Additionally, they maintain red<strong>und</strong>ant relations<br />
to suppliers that may be harked back to in times<br />
of shortages. Even though the intimate suppliers<br />
are evaluated as much more important<br />
for the merchants’ business performance, it<br />
must be mentioned that both goals, a broadening<br />
and a deepening of their network relations,<br />
are on the businessmen’s agenda.<br />
Given the perishability and seasonality of rice<br />
and fish, the traders’ business performance<br />
turns out to be to large extent a question of the<br />
quality of their networks. While rice can be<br />
stored over months, fish rots within few hours<br />
if not properly cooled and looses its value<br />
within a single day. In the absence of cold<br />
stores, fish merchants bear a much higher risk<br />
of making losses. This fact makes fish wholesalers<br />
even more reliant on strong, trustworthy<br />
business relations and ongoing, frictionless<br />
supplies. A young shop owner explains the<br />
consequences of supply shortfalls: “Sometimes<br />
all of my three suppliers can not deliver fish at<br />
the same day. This happens aro<strong>und</strong> 90 days a<br />
year! I can not do business then in these days”<br />
(Interview 3.4. 2009).<br />
The way how business is carried out is shaped<br />
by the immanent institutions which constitute<br />
the relation. The statement of another fish merchant<br />
helps to <strong>und</strong>erstand the difference between<br />
formal and informal relations that holds<br />
relevance for their dealings with both suppliers<br />
and customers. On the informal relations to his<br />
customers he states: “I usually call my permanent<br />
customers to sell them their preferred fish.<br />
Occasional customers come to me independently.<br />
They buy fish only in case they can<br />
make profit. I have a pure business relation to<br />
them. With my permanent customers this is different.<br />
I tell them the purchase price and my<br />
expenses. I add my personal profit and tell<br />
them the price. And they have to buy [the fish]<br />
for that price. Even though other wholesalers<br />
here at the market have better prices, they<br />
would never buy fish from someone else. Because<br />
they have 100 % trust in me!” (Interview<br />
3.4. 2009).<br />
This statement should not be misinterpreted in<br />
the sense that an attitude of individual profit<br />
maximization would dominate only the formal<br />
market arrangements.An attitude of profit maximization<br />
can also be fo<strong>und</strong> in informal relationships.<br />
The above mentioned statements show<br />
that formal market relationships are mainly<br />
maintained to floating customers and to additional,<br />
sometimes red<strong>und</strong>ant suppliers. Since<br />
both exchange partners hardly know each other,<br />
the transaction is agreed upon on the sheer basis<br />
of prices. In stark contrast to that, the traders<br />
share much more information with their close<br />
exchange partners, such as on the conditions of<br />
acquisition and the quality of goods, their personal<br />
expenses and profit margin. Furthermore,<br />
in formal relationships the exchange partners<br />
themselves as well as the relations to them are<br />
appraised as being of no special value. In fact,<br />
the traders have no special word for this kind of<br />
relationsships; they are either called pure business<br />
relation or it is stated that there would not<br />
exist any relation at all. On the contrary, the<br />
traders evaluate the relationships to their close<br />
partners as being of severe importance. This is<br />
expressed in their everyday language as they<br />
circumscribe these relations with several words<br />
such as trust or faith (biswas), commitment<br />
(protigha or protisruti), courage (utshaho) or<br />
honesty (dan).<br />
It is argued here that basically two aspects are<br />
responsible for this value enhancement of informal<br />
relationsships, that is their sentimental<br />
and their instrumental significance (cf. LI<br />
2007, 236). In regard to the sentimental dimension<br />
of informality, a rather short statement of<br />
a rice trader may serve as eye-opener. On the<br />
question of how he perceives his five most important<br />
suppliers he answered briefly: “To<br />
some extent, we are businessmen. But we are<br />
also brothers [bhai, which literally means<br />
brother, but is generally used to express social<br />
proximity]. We are both, brothers and businessmen.”<br />
(Interview 7.4. 2009). What is designative<br />
in this statement is the fact that the<br />
trader does not perceive the two roles of businessman<br />
and brother as two opponents. He<br />
does not draw a clear cutting line that would<br />
separate them. It is rather both roles that are accepted<br />
as being constitutive of the relationship.<br />
If we consider formal relations as being basically<br />
uni-dimensional, as allowing only few<br />
scope for abnormal behaviour between, for instance,<br />
a seller and a buyer, informal relationships<br />
are more diversified and basically multidimensional.<br />
By the means of iterative interaction,<br />
a pure businessman may thus become<br />
gradually a person with various social roles<br />
such as family head, friend, neighbour, religious<br />
fellow and supplier, each one bringing up<br />
another logic and code of conduct. In this context,<br />
LI (2007, 239) speaks of the versatility of
54 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Table 2: Assessment of Business Relations, Rice Wholesalers<br />
Tab. 2: Assessment of business relations, rice wholesalers<br />
“Please consider the relations to your customers and suppliers: What role plays ... for these relations?”<br />
In Relations to Regular In Relations to Occasional Difference<br />
Business Partners (Mean) Business Partners (Mean) (Mean)<br />
The quality of goods Very important (1.00) Very important (1.00) 0.00<br />
To push prices for personal gain Important (2.18) Important (2.32) 0.14<br />
To follow same religion Not important (3.81) Not important (3.96) 0.15<br />
To be relatives Not important (3.60) Not important (3.88) 0.28<br />
To share same home district Not important (3.67) Not important (3.99) 0.32<br />
The reputation of your partner Very important (1.15) Important (1.86) 0.71<br />
To get credit* Important (2.48) Not important (3.60) 1.12<br />
To <strong>und</strong>erstand other’s business* Important (2.01) Rather not important (3.48) 1.47<br />
To do each other a favour* Very important (1.47) Rather not important (3.03) 1.56<br />
To help in difficult times* Very important (1.50) Rather not important (3.09) 1.59<br />
The balance of favours* Important (1.59) Rather not important (3.43) 1.84<br />
To give credit* Very important (1.42) Rather not important (3.41) 1.99<br />
Source: Own Survey 2009�2010<br />
informal relationships. It is argued that the sentimental<br />
value of informal relations is rooted in<br />
this versatility.<br />
The instrumental value of informality gets<br />
clear, for instance, in cases of supply cuts. In<br />
times of low amounts of available goods, suppliers<br />
apply their credo ‘first partners first’ and<br />
deliver their goods to their most valued customers<br />
only, whereas others are missed out.<br />
Thus, informal business relations help the merchants<br />
to get their goods even in difficult times,<br />
when not only the general supply but also the<br />
number of available suppliers decreases. Similarly,<br />
informal relations are helpful in times of<br />
financial shortfalls. Drawing on joint experiences<br />
with another wholesaler at the same market,<br />
whom he calls a business partner, a fish<br />
trader declares: “In case I run out of money today,<br />
I can go to him and borrow some. The next<br />
day I will give it back, no problem” (Interview<br />
3.4. 2009). It is argued here, that it is this “joint<br />
problem solving attitude” (cf. UZZI 1997, 42<br />
ff.) and a behaviour that is first and foremost<br />
committed to maintain and prolong the relationship<br />
to the partner (cf. LI 2007, 236), that<br />
constitutes the instrumental value of informal<br />
relations in Dhaka.<br />
Source: own survey 2009-2010<br />
Note: The single-factor (one-way) analysis of variance (ANOVA) revealed a significant difference between relations<br />
to regular and occasional business partners in regard to the inherent “joint problem solving attitude” with p
Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 55<br />
Table 3: Assessment of Business Relations, Fish Wholesalers<br />
Tab. 3: Assessment of business relations, fish wholesalers<br />
“Please consider the relations to your customers and suppliers: What role plays ... ?”<br />
In Relations to Regular In Relations to Occasional Difference<br />
Business Partners (Mean) Business Partners (Mean) (Mean)<br />
To be relatives Not important (3.59) Not important (3.57) �0.02<br />
The quality of goods Very important (1.00) Very important (1.07) 0.07<br />
To follow same religion Not important (3.71) Not important (3.82) 0.11<br />
To push prices for personal gain Important (2.12) Important (2.33) 0.21<br />
To share same home district Rather not important (3.25) Rather not important (3.49) 0.24<br />
The reputation of your partner Very important (1.35) Important (1.74) 0.39<br />
To get credit* Important (2.46) Not important (3.64) 1.18<br />
The balance of favours* Important (1.71) Rather not important (2.92) 1.21<br />
To <strong>und</strong>erstand other’s business* Important (2.17) Rather not important (3.39) 1.22<br />
To do each other a favour* Important (1.55) Rather not important (2.92) 1.37<br />
To help in difficult times* Very important (1.33) Rather not important (2.76) 1.43<br />
To give credit* Important (1.58) Rather not important (3.47) 1.89<br />
Source: Own Survey 2009�2010<br />
stand each other’s business’, ‘to take credits’,<br />
‘to give credits’, ‘to help each other in difficult<br />
times’, ‘to do each other a favour’, and ‘the<br />
balance of favours’ were evaluated as very important<br />
or important in strong relations, wheras<br />
they played only a marginal or no role in weak<br />
ones. These differences in the evaluation of<br />
business relations to regular and occassional<br />
suppliers and customers clearly indicate the<br />
difference of governance modes that are inherent<br />
in both types of relationships. As such,<br />
these numbers clearly back an <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
of informal relations that exhibit a profo<strong>und</strong><br />
relevance for the traders’ adaptive capacities.<br />
To sum up, in terms of quantity, rice and fish<br />
wholesalers in Dhaka operate only a small<br />
amount of exchanges via formal market relations,<br />
while the majority of transactions is organized<br />
through informal, trust-based relations.<br />
Based on the empirical evidence presented<br />
above, two basic characteristics of such<br />
relations have been revealed, namely their sentimental<br />
and their instrumental value. The sentimental<br />
value is based on the sharing of more<br />
detailed information and a higher degree of<br />
mutual knowledge. It gradually leads to an ever<br />
growing versatility of relationships and thus to<br />
flexibility, options for action, and an atmos-<br />
Source: own survey 2009-2010<br />
Note: The single-factor (one-way) analysis of variance (ANOVA) revealed a significant difference between relations<br />
to regular and occasional business partners in regard to the inherent “joint problem solving attitude” with p
56 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
analysis has extented to the food system of<br />
Dhaka City only as far as food is brought to the<br />
urban markets, not to the ability of final consumers<br />
to buy food. It has been assumed that it<br />
is the continuous effort of food traders and in<br />
particular their constant investment in informal<br />
business relations, that determines the food<br />
system’s robustness to a large extent. Following<br />
LI (2007), informal relations have been <strong>und</strong>erstood<br />
as comprising institutional arrangements<br />
that are implicitly codified, endogenously<br />
imposed, and dealt with in a flexible, personalized<br />
and thus particularistic manner. Informality<br />
is most prominently expressed in<br />
trustworthy relationships. Informal relations<br />
are related to specific transaction qualities and<br />
an inherent value enhancement that stems from<br />
their sentimental and their instrumental character.<br />
In case of Dhaka’s rice and fish wholesalers,<br />
the sentimental value of informal relations<br />
have been shown to stem from their inherent<br />
versatility, whereas the instrumental<br />
value has been fo<strong>und</strong> to originate from the<br />
traders’ joint problem solving activities and<br />
their commitment to maintain and prolong the<br />
relationship to their partners. As such, informal<br />
relations owe the merchants stable and longterm<br />
returns and thus contribute to their overall<br />
business performance. By adding to the traders’<br />
adaptive capacities, it is the web of mutual<br />
trust and social capital that keeps the food system<br />
of Dhaka running.<br />
Especially in megacities, informality is often<br />
interpreted in negative terms as a clear indicator<br />
for an upcoming or even already prevalent<br />
governance crisis. Such a conceptualization,<br />
however, bears the risk to neglect the inherent<br />
potential of informal governance modes for<br />
people’s adaptive capacities and cities’ future<br />
development. If we want to achieve a better <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
of the social mechanisms that foster<br />
societies’ resilience, we need to take into<br />
account also those activities of people which<br />
are not formally regulated by the market or<br />
state and which sometimes even circumvent<br />
statutory measures and policies.<br />
Notes<br />
1 Fish markets that were studied are Kawran Bazar, Jatrabari,<br />
Merul Badda, Sultan Shah, Mugdapara, Dipjol<br />
Bazar, Kochukhet, Kaptan Bazar, and New Market.<br />
Rice markets that were studied are Badamtuli, Mohakali,<br />
Jatrabari, Kochukhet, Mirpur 1, Kawran Bazar,<br />
Uttor Badda, Krishi Market, Boro Bazar, Modda Badda,<br />
West Nakhal Para and Mirpur 10 (see Fig. 1). In<br />
addition to the study on food wholesalers, a second<br />
study focused on the third layer of the food system,<br />
with a specific focus on street food vendors, their<br />
livelihoods, and their daily struggles for accessing<br />
public space (see ETZOLD et al. 2009). A third study<br />
was <strong>und</strong>ertaken on poor slum dwellers, their food consumption<br />
patterns, and the impact of the recent food<br />
price hike on their livelihoods (see ZINGEL et al. 2011).<br />
Unfortunately, results of these latter two studies exceed<br />
the scope of this paper.<br />
2 Wholesalers are defined as business organizations<br />
(ADELSTEIN 2010) that are dedicated to the sale of<br />
products to retailers, street food vendors or restaurant<br />
owners, or more generally, to anyone other than final<br />
consumers. Usually, rice is sold in 50 to 80 kg sacks<br />
rather than in smaller portions; fish is sold in b<strong>und</strong>les<br />
of baskets or drums, not per piece or per kg. – Markets<br />
are defined as a composition of wholesalers in direct<br />
spatial proximity to each other at a specific place. In<br />
Dhaka, these markets are sometimes precisely bordered,<br />
as it is the case if they are planned and installed<br />
by the municipality. Sometimes they are somewhat<br />
fuzzy in their extent, as it is the case if they are privatly<br />
installed with shops that are stringed along a road.<br />
References<br />
ADELSTEIN, R. (2010): Firms as social Actors. In: Journal<br />
of <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics, (6)3, 329-349.<br />
AHMED, R. (2001): Retrospects and prospects of the rice<br />
economy of Bangladesh. Dhaka.<br />
BBS (Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics) (2007): Report<br />
of the household income and expenditure survey 2005.<br />
Dhaka.<br />
BOHLE, H.-G. (2005): Soziales oder unsoziales Kapital?<br />
Das Sozialkapital-Konzept in der Geographischen Verw<strong>und</strong>barkeitsforschung.<br />
In: Geographische Zeitschrift,<br />
(93)2, 65-81.<br />
BOHLE, H.-G./ETZOLD, B./KECK, M. (2009): Resilience<br />
as agency. In: International Human Dimensions Programme<br />
on Global Environmental Change Update<br />
2/2009, 8-13. Internet: http://www.ihdp.unu.edu/file/<br />
get/7170; 12.10.2010<br />
BURT, R. (2001): Structural holes versus network closure<br />
as social capital. In: Lin, N./Cook, K./Burt, R.<br />
(Eds.): Social capital. Theory and research. New York,<br />
31-56.<br />
CARR, E. (2008): Between structure and agency. Livelihoods<br />
and adaptation in Ghana’s Central Region. In:<br />
Global Environmental Change, (19)4, 689-699.<br />
CHEN, M. (2006): Rethinking the informal economy.<br />
Linkages with the formal economy and the formal regulatory<br />
environment. In: Guha-Khasnobis, B./Kanbur,<br />
R./Ostrom, E. (Eds.): Linking the formal and informal<br />
economy. Concepts and policies. New York, 75-92.<br />
COLEMAN, J. (1990): Fo<strong>und</strong>ations of social theory. Cambridge,<br />
London.<br />
DE SOYSA, I./JÜTTING, J. (2007): Informal institutions<br />
and development. How they matter and what makes<br />
them change. In: Jütting, J./Drechsler, D./Bartsch, S./de<br />
Soysa, I. (Eds.): Informal institutions. How social<br />
norms help or hinder development. Paris, 29-43.
Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 57<br />
(OECD - Development Centre Studies)<br />
DEVEREUX, S. (Ed.)(2007): The new famines. Why<br />
famines persist in an era of globalization. London/New<br />
York.<br />
DOROSH, P./DE NINNO, C./SHAHABUDDIN, Q. (2004):<br />
Overview of the Bangladesh foodgrain economy. In: De<br />
Ninno, C./Shahabuddin, Q./Dorosh, P. (Eds.): The 1998<br />
floods and beyond. Towards comprehensive food security<br />
in Bangladesh. Dhaka, 13-52.<br />
DOROSH, P./MURSHID, K. (2004): Trade liberalization<br />
and national food security. Rice trade between<br />
Bangladesh and India. In: De Ninno, C./Shahabuddin,<br />
Q./Dorosh, P. (Eds.): The 1998 floods and beyond. Towards<br />
comprehensive food security in Bangladesh.<br />
Dhaka, 101-126.<br />
ERICKSON, P. (2008): Conceptualizing food systems for<br />
global environmental change research. In: Global Environmental<br />
Change, (18)1, 234-245.<br />
ETZOLD, B./KECK, M./BOHLE, H.-G./ZINGEL, W.-P.<br />
(2009): Informality as agency – negotiating food security<br />
in Dhaka. In: Die Erde, (140)1, 3-24.<br />
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization)(2008): Rice<br />
market monitor. Washington D.C. (April 2008, vol. XI,<br />
issue 1).<br />
FAO (2009a) Rice market monitor. Washington D.C.<br />
(Feb. 2009. vol. XII, issue 1).<br />
FAO (2009b) Rice market monitor. Washington D.C.<br />
(Dec. 2009, vol. VII, issue 2).<br />
FAOSTAT (2010): Database on food production and<br />
trade. Internet: http://faostat.fao.org/default.aspx,<br />
12.10.2010<br />
FPMU (Food Policy Monitoring Unit) (2009):<br />
Bangladesh food situation report, 78. Dhaka.<br />
GIDDENS, A. (1984): The constitution of society. Outline<br />
of the theory of structuration. Cambridge.<br />
GLÜCKLER, J. (2001): Zur Bedeutung von Embeddedness<br />
in der <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>. In: Geographische<br />
Zeitschrift, (89)4, 211-226.<br />
GRANOVETTER, M. (1973): The strength of weak ties. In:<br />
American Journal of Sociology, (78)6, 1360-1380.<br />
GRANOVETTER, M. (1985): Economic action and economic<br />
structure. The problem of embeddedness. In:<br />
American Journal of Sociology, (91)3, 481-510.<br />
GUYER, J. (1987): Introduction. In: Guyer, J. (Ed): Feeding<br />
African cities. Studies in regional social history.<br />
Manchester, 1-54.<br />
HART, K. (1973): Informal income opportunities and urban<br />
employment in Ghana. In: Journal of Modern<br />
African Studies, (11)1, 61-89.<br />
ILO (International Labor Organization)(1972): Employment,<br />
incomes and equality. A strategy for increasing<br />
productive employment in Kenya. Geneva.<br />
ISLAM, N. (2005): Dhaka now. Contemporary urban development.<br />
Dhaka. (Bangladesh Geographical Society).<br />
ISLAM, N. (2010): Dhaka in 2050. In: CUS Bulletin on<br />
Urbanization and Development, (58/59), 5-10<br />
KECK, M./ETZOLD, B./BOHLE, H.-G./ZINGEL, W.-P.<br />
(2008): Reis <strong>für</strong> die Megacity. Nahrungsversorgung von<br />
Dhaka zwischen globalen Risiken <strong>und</strong> lokalen Verw<strong>und</strong>barkeiten.<br />
In: Geographische R<strong>und</strong>schau, (60)11, 28-37.<br />
KRAAS, F. (2008): Megacities as global risk areas. In:<br />
Marzluff, J./Endlicher, W./Alberti, M./Bradley,<br />
G./Ryan, C./ZumBrunnen, C./Simon, U. (Eds.): Urban<br />
ecology. An international perspective on the interaction<br />
between humans and nature. New York, 583-596.<br />
KRAAS, F./NITSCHKE, U. (2006): Megastädte als Motoren<br />
globalen Wandels. Neue Herausforderungen weltweiter<br />
Urbanisierung. In: Internationale Politik, (61)11,<br />
18-28.<br />
KRAAS, F./MERTINS, G. (2008): Megastädte in Entwicklungsländern.<br />
Vulnerabilität, Informalität, Regier- <strong>und</strong><br />
Steuerbarkeit. In: Geographische R<strong>und</strong>schau, (60)11, 4-<br />
10.<br />
KUMAR, S. (2002): Methods for community participation.<br />
A complete guide for practitioners. London.<br />
LI, P. (2007): Social tie, social capital, and social behavior.<br />
Toward an integrative model of informal exchange.<br />
In: Asia Pacific Journal of Management, (24)2,<br />
227-246.<br />
NORTH, D. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change and<br />
economic performance. New York.<br />
NORTH, D. (2005): Understanding the process of economic<br />
change. Princeton/Oxford.<br />
PORTES, A. (1998): Social capital. Its origins and applications<br />
in modern sociology. In: Annual Review of Sociology,<br />
24, 1-24.<br />
PUTNAM, R. (1993): Making democracy work. Civic traditions<br />
in modern Italy. New York.<br />
SCOTT, R. (2008): <strong>Institut</strong>ions and organizations. Ideas<br />
and interest. London.<br />
SEARLE, J. (1995): The construction of social reality.<br />
London.<br />
SIDDIQUI, K./AHMED, J./AWAL, A./AHMED, M. (2000):<br />
Overcoming the governance crisis in Dhaka City. Dhaka.<br />
UN (United Nations - Department of Economic and Social<br />
Affairs, Population Division)(2008): World urbanization<br />
prospects. The 2007 revision. Internet: http:<br />
//www.un.org/ esa/ population/ publications/ wup2007/<br />
2007WUP_Highlights_web.pdf, 12.10.2010<br />
UZZI, B. (1996): The sources and consequences of embeddedness<br />
for the economic performance of organizations.<br />
The network effect. In: American Sociological<br />
Review, (61)4, 674-698.<br />
UZZI, B. (1997): Social structure and competition in interfirm<br />
networks. The paradox of embeddedness. In:<br />
Administrative Science Quarterly, (42)1, 35-67.<br />
WATTS, M. (1983): Silent violence. Food, famine and<br />
peasantry in Northern Nigeria. Berkeley.<br />
World Bank (2007): Dhaka. Improving living conditions<br />
of the urban poor. Dhaka. (The World Bank Office,<br />
Dhaka). Internet: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/<br />
B A N G L A D E S H E X T N / R e s o u r c e s / 2 9 5 7 5 9 -<br />
1182963268987/dhakaurbanreport.pdf, 12.10.2010<br />
ZINGEL, W.-P./KECK, M./ETZOLD, B./BOHLE, H.-G.<br />
(2011): Urban food security and health risks in Dhaka. In:<br />
Krämer, A./Khan, M./Kraas, F. (Eds.): Health in megacities<br />
and urban areas. New York/Heidelberg, 301-319.
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 58-79<br />
Pamela Hartmann Kilian, Köln/ Daniel Schiller, Hannover/ Frauke Kraas, Köln<br />
Workplace quality and labour turnover in the electronics industry<br />
of the Pearl River Delta, China<br />
Contrasting employer and employee perspectives<br />
Abstract: Export-oriented manufacturing firms in developing countries need to be highly flexible<br />
in order to respond to demand changes in volatile global markets. By using a modified version of<br />
Atkinson’s flexible firm concept as a framework, it is the aim of this paper (i) to describe the impact<br />
of workplace quality on labour turnover and (ii) to derive implications of this relationship for<br />
upgrading processes. Empirical data are combined from two surveys of migrant workers and electronics<br />
firms in the Pearl River Delta, China.<br />
Keywords: flexible firm, upgrading, workplace quality, labour turnover, China<br />
Introduction<br />
Since the implementation of China’s opening<br />
policy (1978), the Pearl River Delta in the<br />
southern region of the country has developed<br />
into the so-called ‘factory of the world’ for<br />
flexible and wage-sensitive production in<br />
labour-intensive sectors of light industry (EN-<br />
RIGHT et al. 2005). One of the most important<br />
sectors involved in this rise is the electronics<br />
industry, which is responsible for approximately<br />
39 % of the value added of the region<br />
(GDSTATS 2010) and is particularly tightly integrated<br />
into globally organised value chains<br />
(MEYER et al. 2009; MEYER et al. 2012; STUR-<br />
GEON 2002). The Pearl River Delta, with its<br />
large growth dynamic for industrial value<br />
added and its flexible production model, is subject<br />
to strong cyclical deviations, both seasonal<br />
and related to its dependence on exports.<br />
During the most recent global economic and financial<br />
crisis, the growth rate of the gross domestic<br />
product (GDP) in Guangdong fell from<br />
10.5 % in 2008 to 5.8 % in the first quarter of<br />
2009 (YU/ZHANG 2009) – and in Dongguan<br />
even more so, from 14.0 % to -3.5 % (YU/<br />
HUANG 2009).<br />
Moreover, the shortage of workers, which was<br />
already a problem before the crisis (HE 2006;<br />
YANG 2005), has now been making headlines<br />
once again since 2010 following a short interruption<br />
during the crisis years (The Economist<br />
29.7. 2010, KNIGHT et al. 2011). The financial<br />
crisis was only temporarily able to mask the<br />
demographic effects of the one child policy,<br />
which are becoming apparent in that the 18-24<br />
years age group, which is so important for industrial<br />
companies, is shrinking. An additional<br />
problem is the fact that the economic development<br />
of the inland regions of China is providing<br />
increasingly attractive job opportunities for<br />
migrant workers in their home provinces, and<br />
the demands of the younger generation of<br />
workers are beginning to increase. The current<br />
generation is less willing than previous ones to<br />
accept the low quality of jobs, i.e. the often<br />
monotonous, physically straining and dangerous<br />
working conditions, in relation to the financial<br />
rewards, further benefits and qualification<br />
requirements (YUE et al. 2010). Companies<br />
are thus complaining of high rates of<br />
labour turnover, with a personnel substitution<br />
rate of 30-40 % per year being a fairly midrange<br />
figure (HÜRTGEN et al. 2009, 226); for<br />
companies with foreign investment, the<br />
turnover rate is estimated to be between 30 %<br />
and 90 % (PUN/SMITH 2007, 36 ff.), since job<br />
changing, i.e. employees moving to another<br />
company, is triggered initially by minimal differences<br />
in wage costs, and is also generally<br />
possible without any significant difficulties<br />
due to homogeneous and weak regulation, low<br />
qualification requirements and low demands of<br />
the positions on workers.
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 59<br />
Against this backgro<strong>und</strong>, CHAN (2010a) speaks<br />
of a Chinese paradox consisting of a shortage<br />
of migrant workers in the coastal provinces<br />
and a surplus of labour supply in the rural regions.<br />
In his opinion, the Lewisian turning<br />
point (LEWIS 1954), at which the unlimited<br />
supply of labour from rural areas dries up and<br />
wages steadily begin to increase, has not yet<br />
been reached. The Hukou system and an increased<br />
demand for workers in rural areas<br />
stemming from the 2009 economic stimulus<br />
package have had a particularly distorting effect<br />
on price formation on the job market. The<br />
former worsens the negotiation position of rural<br />
workers in the coastal regions, while the latter<br />
has led to a temporary rise in the number of<br />
non-agricultural job possibilities in rural regions.<br />
CHAN (2010b) does not expect the situation<br />
of workers or the stability of working conditions<br />
to change unless the access to a local<br />
Hukou at the job location is simplified. The<br />
first signs of this are evident in the province of<br />
Guangdong, which is most heavily affected by<br />
the current shortage of workers, in that it is<br />
aiming to provide 1.8 million qualified migrant<br />
workers with a local Hukou within the next<br />
three years (CHAN 2010a).<br />
In the following hypothesis it will be examined<br />
that the labour market in the region is caught in<br />
an inefficient ‘lock-in’ situation, i.e. trapped in<br />
a situation in which the incentive structures do<br />
not lead to investment in qualification on the<br />
part of companies and workers. Workers are<br />
not primarily interested in long-term qualifications,<br />
but rather in short-term income maximisation.<br />
Companies make virtually no investment<br />
in qualification measures and improved<br />
working conditions, since these are not honoured<br />
by increased loyalty on the part of workers,<br />
and, due to the short-term orientation of<br />
the business model, are not necessary either. In<br />
the long term, however, this hampers – and<br />
sometimes even blocks – the upgrading process<br />
towards better quality production and<br />
qualification as well as more stable employment<br />
conditions.<br />
Two questions are at the centre of this investigation:<br />
– To what extent do the quality of jobs and<br />
employee characteristics influence job<br />
changes <strong>und</strong>ertaken by employees and the<br />
labour turnover in companies?<br />
– Does a qualification lock-in exist in the electronics<br />
industry of the Pearl River Delta in<br />
the area of labour-intensive and wage-sensitive<br />
production, and if so, how can this be<br />
overcome?<br />
Firstly, basic theoretical principles concerning<br />
the connection between flexibility and company<br />
success will be discussed, and determinants<br />
for job change will be demarcated. Quantitative<br />
survey data from companies and workers<br />
will be combined methodically. On this basis,<br />
workplace quality and its variation as well as<br />
the influence of workplace quality on the employee<br />
turnover rate of the companies will be<br />
determined, followed by a summary of the results<br />
and a derivation of policy recommendations.<br />
Flexible company organisation<br />
and labour turnover<br />
The term flexibility established itself in this<br />
context in the 1980s and was taken up by international<br />
organisations (e.g. OECD, IMF)<br />
and governments from the 1990s onwards.<br />
This promoted a normative research dialogue<br />
regarding the necessity of flexibilisation of<br />
company organisation and the erosion of normal<br />
working conditions in the course of a farreaching<br />
flexibilisation of companies. As a<br />
counterpoint to this, REILLY (1998) called for a<br />
more detailed differentiation of flexibility requirements<br />
and the empirical investigation of<br />
flexibility potential at the individual, company<br />
and regulation levels.<br />
The flexible firm in the Chinese context<br />
Flexibilisation in the Western context aims to<br />
increase adaptability within an existing political-economic<br />
system. However, this development<br />
must be categorised very differently in<br />
the Chinese context with its gradual socio-economic<br />
transformation to a market economy.<br />
There, the newly formed private economic sector<br />
has been geared towards a high degree of<br />
flexibility from the beginning. It is clearly evident<br />
that the organisation of manufacturing<br />
companies in the Pearl River Delta is characterised<br />
by a tight integration into global production<br />
processes. The volatility of demand<br />
connected to this requires a high degree of<br />
flexibility in terms of production volumes. But<br />
how do these market requirements translate to<br />
the level of company organisation?
60 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Fig. 1: The flexible firm in the context of Chinese low-cost production<br />
Source: own draft, based on ATKINSON 1984, 29<br />
ALBRECHT (2002, 2005) has produced studies<br />
on flexibilisation in German-speaking geography<br />
which refer in their typology of flexibility<br />
to earlier works from the field of company research.<br />
ATKINSON (1984) developed the first<br />
typology of flexibility forms within companies.<br />
According to him, various workforce<br />
groups contribute in different ways to increasing<br />
the flexibility of a company through their<br />
own flexible deployment: the core workforce<br />
of long-term employees should be flexible in<br />
the carrying out of their function. The peripheral<br />
workforce, which makes up the largest<br />
number of employees, is affected by numerical<br />
and financial flexibility (Fig. 1). Numerical<br />
flexibility refers to a varying number of employees<br />
depending on the needs of the company;<br />
financial flexibility concerns the wage policy<br />
of the company being linked to fluctuations<br />
in demand, and in the Western context,<br />
also measures such as commission on profits.<br />
Under certain circumstances though, the advantage<br />
of an efficiently controllable person-<br />
nel volume, which may be achieved through<br />
flexible company organisation, can actually become<br />
a disadvantage. Numerical flexibility, for<br />
instance, involves considerable costs for recruitment<br />
and training. Even though WHITELEY<br />
et al. (2000) estimate these costs to be lower<br />
than those for a regularisation of the workforce,<br />
a high fluctuation can prove to be a liability<br />
for companies in China, especially in a<br />
situation of job surplus and labour shortage<br />
(JIANG et al. 2009).<br />
ATKINSONs flexibility typology has, until now,<br />
only been further differentiated for the Western<br />
investigation context (e.g. REILLY 1998; VAL-<br />
VERDE et al. 2000), which is of little use for the<br />
Chinese context. For example, subcategories of<br />
the peripheral workforce, which are widespread<br />
in the context of the USA and Europe, and particularly<br />
in The Netherlands and Great Britain<br />
(part-time and formalised temporary work, job<br />
sharing, as well as publicly subsidised professional<br />
training within companies), are still
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 61<br />
generally absent from the manufacturing companies<br />
in China. There, a third, purposely unregulated<br />
segment of the labour market is developing<br />
in the course of the transformation process<br />
between a rural and urban economy: a<br />
market segment of migrant workers (míngōng)<br />
(HEBEL/SCHUCHER 2006). This initiative designed<br />
to mobilise labour resources is well<br />
known as a success factor for China’s economic<br />
boom, but at the expense of social security,<br />
since the migrant workers, of which there<br />
are more than 200 million, must retain their<br />
primary residence in their home towns <strong>und</strong>er<br />
this so-called Hukou system. This means that<br />
access to the social security system at their<br />
work locations has so far remained blocked for<br />
them (health insurance, pension schemes, unemployment<br />
insurance and the subsidised<br />
accommodation market, along with school<br />
education). This results in much lower personnel<br />
costs for companies for these migrant<br />
workers than those for the locally registered<br />
workers, but in wages which are still much<br />
more attractive for the migrant workers than<br />
those in their home regions, thus creating the<br />
basis for the competitive advantage of Chinese<br />
production companies over other production<br />
locations. Activities in low-cost production requiring<br />
little or no qualification, which form<br />
the focal point of employee-based investigations,<br />
are almost exclusively carried out by migrant<br />
workers. Such employment arrangements<br />
are often short-term (up to one year, linshi<br />
zhigong) and rarely mid to long-term (changqi<br />
zhigong) (STAIGER 2008). These considerations<br />
lead to a modified conception of the flexible<br />
firm (Fig. 1).<br />
Due to the high degree of quantitative flexibilisation<br />
in the production companies, it is to be<br />
expected that the workforce is strongly segregated,<br />
also in terms of qualifications. Qualification-based<br />
segregation is defined in this case<br />
as the concentration of employees with a certain<br />
qualification level within a company, although<br />
differing qualification standards certainly<br />
exist between companies (GERLACH et al.<br />
2002). Through outsourcing of production activities,<br />
qualification-based segregation is generally<br />
on the increase (TSERTSVADZE 2005).<br />
Because of the specialisation of Chinese companies<br />
in simpler production activities, segregation<br />
within the global value chain means that<br />
in China, a very small proportion of highly<br />
qualified core workers is juxtaposed in the<br />
manufacturing industry with a large proportion<br />
of poorly qualified migrant workers in the peripheral<br />
workforces for simple production activities.<br />
In contrast, the globally active customer<br />
firms in industrial countries are characterised<br />
by an increasing proportion of highly<br />
qualified employees.<br />
The effects of qualification-based segregation<br />
in internal company learning processes have<br />
not yet been empirically verified. From a conceptional<br />
perspective, however, it can be assumed<br />
that a functional and qualification-based<br />
specialisation that is too one-sided will have<br />
negative effects on learning and will make the<br />
transition of employees from the peripheral to<br />
the core workforce more difficult. Such mobility,<br />
however, would be a starting point for<br />
technological and organisational upgrading<br />
processes, since the building up of basic technological<br />
capabilities is often a result of continual<br />
incremental improvements and knowledge<br />
stemming from experience (KIM 1997), with<br />
the increase of absorptive capacity through<br />
qualified human resources also playing a decisive<br />
role (COHEN/LEVINTHAL 1990). The empirical<br />
investigation of this research project thus<br />
concentrates particularly on the examination of<br />
the peripheral (production and migrant workers)<br />
and their potential role for upgrading<br />
processes.<br />
In accordance with the segregation theory, an<br />
observation of the Chinese electronics industry<br />
clearly shows that the sector is characterised by<br />
a high degree of heterogeneity. On the one<br />
hand, there is the small number of technologically<br />
very active companies which receive almost<br />
unlimited support from the state and have<br />
established international innovation activities,<br />
while on the other hand, there is the vast majority<br />
of companies which possess virtually no<br />
technological competences or absorptive capacity<br />
(ERNST/NAUGHTON 2008). The two sectors<br />
of the branch coexist almost entirely separate<br />
from one another, meaning that knowledge<br />
spillover and the development of a coherent innovation<br />
system cannot realistically be expected<br />
(KROLL/SCHILLER 2011).<br />
Flexibility, workplace quality and labour<br />
turnover<br />
Against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of the transformation<br />
processes in China and their overriding influence<br />
on increased labour turnover, possible determinants<br />
for a change of jobs at the company<br />
level will be discussed, both from an employee
62 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
(supply) and employer (demand) perspective.<br />
Employer perspective: In accordance with the<br />
flexibility maxim, a company aims for an efficiently<br />
directed personnel volume suited to the<br />
current demand situation. The varying need for<br />
labour must thus be seen as the most important<br />
determinant from the company point of view<br />
for labour turnover. In this specific context, it<br />
is managed through contracts and simplified<br />
through a weakly regulated environment (SHEN<br />
2007; LÜTHJE 2008; HÜRTGEN et al. 2009). The<br />
conditions determining workplace quality are<br />
geared to a large extent towards financial flexibility,<br />
and are thus only marginally focused on<br />
the provision of consistent social welfare measures.<br />
Cost advantages are the principal determining<br />
factor behind decisions and generally<br />
entail an achievement-based wage policy in<br />
companies.<br />
Of particular importance in terms of upgrading<br />
processes from the company perspective are<br />
also the human resources available and the<br />
qualification of workers present within the<br />
company. Qualification measures consist here<br />
of education programmes upon entry into the<br />
company or both internal and external further<br />
education programmes provided by the firm.<br />
Qualification of workers in the production area<br />
is potentially beneficial for a transition to the<br />
core workforce and for the reduction of labour<br />
turnover through greater job security, more diverse<br />
spectra of activity and improved income<br />
possibilities. For the empirical investigation,<br />
on the other hand, it can be suspected that the<br />
probability of a job change increases if the expected<br />
educational benefits following a qualification<br />
initiative do not materialise for an individual<br />
employee. Particularly for large labour<br />
markets – such as the Pearl River Delta – the<br />
expectation is that the incentive for companies<br />
to invest in further education diminishes, since<br />
changes in personnel increase following further<br />
education due to the larger number of alternative<br />
employment options for workers, and<br />
because the relevant qualification requirements<br />
can be obtained by companies through the<br />
labour market (BRANDT 2009). However, an<br />
empirical investigation is still required in order<br />
to determine whether this hypothesis derived<br />
from the Western context can be applied to the<br />
Chinese situation.<br />
Employee perspective: Employees (Fig. 1, peripheral<br />
workforce), a heterogeneous research<br />
group, may be categorised according to characteristics<br />
such as age, gender, education and occupation.<br />
When considering labour turnover,<br />
one must take into account how important various<br />
company benefits are to the different<br />
groups of employees and what benefits they indeed<br />
encounter in companies. The conditions<br />
provided in companies can be categorised according<br />
to physical, social and organisational<br />
factors, as well as the company benefits mentioned<br />
above.<br />
In the context of Chinese companies, three aspects<br />
are of particular importance for the <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
of workplace quality and labour<br />
turnover. Firstly, there has been a change in the<br />
attitude among migrant workers, which still<br />
constitute the largest proportion of poorly qualified<br />
employees. In this case, however, it is not<br />
so much the Lewisian ‘turning point’ which is<br />
able to explain the shortage of labour and rising<br />
wages (CHAN 2010a), but rather the increased<br />
demands of the second generation of<br />
migrant workers in terms of their working conditions<br />
and environment, since alternative vocational<br />
possibilities are now emerging in the<br />
peripheral regions and there is a current tendency<br />
towards a reduction in the importance of<br />
family support in favour of other migration<br />
motives and strategies (FAN 2008; YUE et al.<br />
2010). Secondly, wages are the central argument<br />
for the selection or change of jobs, although<br />
it is not only the amount which plays a<br />
significant role, but also the reliability of wage<br />
payments, since non-payment of wages is the<br />
most common cause of industrial conflict<br />
(SHEN 2007). Thirdly, social welfare benefits<br />
must be categorised differently in China to the<br />
way in which this is done in Europe. Accommodation,<br />
food and recreational activities are<br />
often all provided by the company, although<br />
this is primarily done for the purpose of exercising<br />
better control over employees on the<br />
company site (PUN 2005). Against the backgro<strong>und</strong><br />
of the changing attitude of migrant<br />
workers, this old model of total provision of<br />
amenities is starting to become less attractive.<br />
Data and methods<br />
The data used for the present investigation encompass<br />
the perspectives of both the companies<br />
and the employees and were gathered using<br />
two standardised questionnaires. These<br />
were carried out in cooperation with the De-
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 63<br />
partment of Urban and Regional Planning of<br />
Sun Yat-sen University in Guangzhou and were<br />
completed at the beginning of 2008. The coupling<br />
of the two sets of survey results is a particularly<br />
fruitful endeavour, especially as it allows<br />
for the capturing of both workplace quality<br />
and job change from the perspective of<br />
employees, as well as the company view of the<br />
workforce and the effects of job changes on the<br />
companies themselves. Several different parameters<br />
were investigated in the course of the<br />
surveys, among both companies and workers<br />
(e.g. wage levels, other benefits, qualification),<br />
in order to achieve a validation of the data<br />
through a comparison of results.<br />
Company data<br />
The data for the company perspective were<br />
taken from a standardised survey of 222 electronics<br />
firms in the Pearl River Delta. The survey<br />
was conducted in cities with a large proportion<br />
of companies from the electronics industry.<br />
The data set encompasses 90 companies<br />
in Dongguan and 116 in Guangzhou. The companies<br />
in Dongguan were selected using the<br />
Guangdong Electronics Company Catalogue<br />
2007; in Guangzhou, a list of companies from<br />
the Municipal Bureau of Statistics was used.<br />
300 questionnaires (150 per city) were distributed<br />
to randomly selected companies following<br />
an introductory telephone conversation in advance.<br />
The response rate was 59 % for Dongguan<br />
and 77 % for Guangzhou. Telephone follow-up<br />
efforts were successful in raising the<br />
quality of survey answers and in reducing the<br />
number of unanswered questions to a minimum.<br />
Due to a lack of structural company information<br />
(e.g. size or owner) in the lists used<br />
to select the samples, a test of representativeness<br />
was not possible. The high response rate,<br />
however, reduces the danger of a systematically<br />
distorted non-answering of questions.<br />
The section of the company survey pertaining<br />
to employees, which is relevant for this study,<br />
contained only closed questions in order to<br />
make it easier to provide answers by telephone<br />
or post. The companies were particularly asked<br />
to make statements about the workers identified<br />
as belonging to the peripheral workforce,<br />
which, in the Pearl River Delta, mostly consists<br />
of migrant workers. Furthermore, a distinction<br />
was often made in the data set during the analysis<br />
between the 114 private Chinese firms and<br />
the 102 foreign companies (including Hong<br />
Kong and Taiwan), since a further aim was to<br />
determine whether the two groups also differ in<br />
terms of workplace quality and flexibility as<br />
they do in terms of technological competences<br />
(SCHILLER 2011).<br />
Employee data<br />
The primary data used for the employee perspective<br />
were taken from a social geography<br />
field study which consisted of both a standardised<br />
survey of 585 workers (of which 566 cases<br />
were suitable for analysis) and a qualitative<br />
collection of data. The latter included 35 interviews<br />
with migrant workers, representatives of<br />
authorities, organisations and employment<br />
agencies as well as participating and non-participating<br />
observations in the factories and the<br />
working environment of low-cost manufacturing.<br />
Considering this large amount of data, this<br />
study will concentrate on the survey data.<br />
The decisive criteria for the selection of the investigation<br />
area and the sample were that it<br />
should be a manufacturing location with a large<br />
proportion of low-cost production in the electronics<br />
industry where the above-mentioned<br />
data could be gathered. This selection process<br />
was faced with the following limitations: 1. a<br />
target group, which can only be captured exploratively<br />
(migrant workers); 2. politically related<br />
restrictions for domestic and foreign<br />
scholars, as well as for the investigation group<br />
in China.<br />
Migrant workers are highly mobile, meaning<br />
that only a small proportion of them are covered<br />
statistically by local authorities, with the<br />
majority only being registered with the companies<br />
which employ them. The choice was made<br />
not to seek access to the subjects via companies,<br />
for example those participating in the<br />
above-mentioned company survey, since no<br />
guarantee could be made that company management<br />
would not influence the statements of<br />
respondents. However, the alternative methods<br />
of gathering data, i.e. in the public sphere, required<br />
legitimisation from public authorities.<br />
The Chinese partner institute of the study<br />
maintains research contacts with Tangxiazhen<br />
in Dongguan, which legitimised the gathering<br />
of the data. With the knowledge that other locations<br />
in the Delta are also specialised in the<br />
electronics industry (e.g. Shilong, Chang’an),<br />
Tangxiazhen was deemed suitable for the data<br />
collection, since the industry there is dominated<br />
by low-cost manufacturing for the export<br />
economy with a large proportion of electronics
64 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
companies. The industrial, demographic and<br />
accompanying socio-economic transformation<br />
processes there are typical for the eastern axis<br />
of the Pearl River Delta (KILIAN et al. 2010).<br />
The sample selection took place in two steps:<br />
First, two areas dominated by the electronics<br />
industry were selected (cluster sampling). The<br />
inner-city industry district 138 (304 valid<br />
questionnaires) has been well established<br />
since the middle of the 1990s. The peri-urban<br />
district Keyuancheng (262 valid questionnaires)<br />
has been occupied by companies since<br />
2005 and is still <strong>und</strong>ergoing development. In<br />
the second step, migrant workers were handed<br />
a questionnaire on the way from the company<br />
site to the shopping street which they filled out<br />
on the spot and returned immediately. Of those<br />
who accepted the questionnaire, the response<br />
rate was 100 %, although some of the questionnaires<br />
were not filled out completely. The<br />
scope of the sample is thus individually labelled.<br />
Workplace quality and labour<br />
turnover<br />
Company perspective<br />
In accordance with the distinction mentioned<br />
above, workplace quality from the company<br />
perspective is measured using the factors income,<br />
social welfare benefits, the design of<br />
employment contracts, training and further education<br />
programmes, and qualification of<br />
workers. The flexibilisation of working conditions<br />
is then investigated using the turnover<br />
rate, the variation in the number of workers<br />
throughout the year, the length of time required<br />
to increase the number of employees by<br />
10 %, as well as typical problems with the<br />
workforce. A differentiation is made between<br />
Chinese and foreign companies, as well as between<br />
Chinese companies at different locations<br />
and of different sizes for selected indicators.<br />
Workplace Quality: The average monthly<br />
wages of the companies surveyed, at approximately<br />
1,300 Yuan, were fo<strong>und</strong> to be well<br />
above the legal minimum wage of 780 Yuan in<br />
Guangzhou and 680 Yuan in Dongguan at the<br />
time of the survey (2007). This suggests that<br />
the labour shortage discussed in the introduction,<br />
which has created particularly strong<br />
competition for qualified workers and for pay-<br />
ment benefits not affecting the basic minimum<br />
wage, for example for overtime, night shift<br />
bonuses, gratuities, had already driven wages<br />
upwards prior to that time. As of May 2010, the<br />
minimum wage was adjusted once again to<br />
1,030 Yuan in Guangzhou and 920 Yuan in<br />
Dongguan (HKTDC 2010). In the survey data,<br />
no significant differences can be fo<strong>und</strong> between<br />
Chinese and foreign companies, which<br />
contradicts the frequently proposed assumption<br />
that foreign companies have an advantage<br />
when competing for labour resources due to<br />
higher wages.<br />
Questions about five benefits provided by<br />
companies over and above the standard wages<br />
revealed that almost 90 % of companies offer<br />
accommodation in a company residential<br />
home, and nearly as many also provide meals<br />
as well as health and accident insurance. Paid<br />
holiday and gifts on festive occasions, especially<br />
at New Year, are much less widespread,<br />
but nevertheless standard at least for half of the<br />
companies surveyed. The social welfare benefits<br />
provided by foreign companies tend to be<br />
slightly greater than those of Chinese companies,<br />
although the differences are only significant<br />
for health and accident insurance. When<br />
combining wages and social welfare benefits,<br />
therefore, only a marginal advantage for foreign<br />
companies could be fo<strong>und</strong>. At this point it<br />
must be taken into consideration that the social<br />
welfare benefits investigated here must be interpreted<br />
differently within the Chinese context<br />
from the way in which they are seen in Europe.<br />
In this regard, PUN (2005) points to the controlling<br />
function of company residential<br />
homes. A high degree of social benefits of this<br />
kind thus characterises those companies which<br />
still follow the classical production model,<br />
which is increasingly coming to be considered<br />
unattractive by the younger generation of migrant<br />
workers.<br />
Two-thirds of employment contracts were individually<br />
negotiated and concluded in written<br />
form. The practice of verbal contracts, which is<br />
illegal <strong>und</strong>er the new Chinese employment<br />
contracts law of 2008 (GEFFKEN et al. 2010) is<br />
now very rare, even among Chinese companies,<br />
although it is still significantly more important<br />
in these firms than in foreign companies.<br />
Due to the minimal importance of verbal<br />
contracts, no investigation has been made as to<br />
their effects on the rate of labour turnover.
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 65<br />
Tab.1: Selected indicators of workplace quality from the company perspective<br />
Indicator Chinese Foreign<br />
Monthly wage in Yuan 1,304 1,250<br />
F-test (sign.) 0.440<br />
Social welfare benefits<br />
Meals 86 % 79 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.192<br />
Accommodation 90 % 87%<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.595<br />
Health/accident<br />
insurance 74 % 86 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.024<br />
Paid holiday 68 % 75 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.279<br />
Gifts on festive<br />
occasions 45 % 53 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.256<br />
Employment contracts<br />
individual written 64 % 66 %<br />
F-test (sign.) 0.691<br />
Individual verbal 11 % 5 %<br />
F-test (sign.) 0.030<br />
Collective 7 % 15 %<br />
F-test (sign.) 0.671<br />
Employment agency<br />
and others 9 % 15 %<br />
F-test (sign.) 0.161<br />
Source: own calculation, company survey 2008<br />
Concerning training and further education, the<br />
following results emerged: much fewer than<br />
half of the companies offer training and further<br />
education measures very frequently. Training<br />
and learning phases occur most often when<br />
new workers commence employment with the<br />
company, while further education is only regularly<br />
offered internally in every fifth company<br />
and externally by every tenth company. Foreign<br />
companies offer significantly more possibilities<br />
in this area of formal training, as well as<br />
in cooperation with external providers of further<br />
education. In the areas of informal training<br />
and internal further education, the differences<br />
are not significant.<br />
Indicator Chinese Foreign<br />
Training and further<br />
education programmes<br />
Formal<br />
training very often (5) 50 % 63 %<br />
programme sometimes/<br />
for new often (3-4) 31 % 29 %<br />
employees never/<br />
rarely (1-2) 19 % 8 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.035<br />
Informal very often (5) 45 % 47 %<br />
training of sometimes/<br />
new often (3-4) 41 % 45 %<br />
employees never/<br />
rarely (1-2) 14 % 8 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.356<br />
Internal very often (5) 22 % 22 %<br />
further sometimes/<br />
education often (3-4) 33 % 40 %<br />
programmes never/<br />
rarely (1-2) 45 % 38 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.499<br />
External very often (5) 11 % 13 %<br />
further sometimes/<br />
education often (3-4) 30 % 42 %<br />
programmes never/<br />
rarely (1-2) 59 % 45 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.104<br />
n = 114 n = 102<br />
With regard to educational qualifications as an<br />
indicator for the qualification of employees, it<br />
could be determined that the group of poorly<br />
qualified workers with no more than a completed<br />
intermediate school education is in the<br />
majority. Approximately another quarter have a<br />
completed secondary school education, with<br />
roughly the same number having a vocational<br />
school qualification, while fewer than 10 %<br />
have a university degree. A surprising finding<br />
was that Chinese companies have more highly<br />
qualified employees on average. The differences<br />
are particularly significant in the area of<br />
vocational school qualifications. This may possibly<br />
be explained by the fact that foreign com-
66 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 2: Selected indicators of job flexibility from the company perspective<br />
Indicator Chinese Foreign Indicator Chinese Foreign<br />
Turnover rate 32 % 40 % Problems with the workforce (continued)<br />
F-test (sign.) 0.072<br />
Job change very often (5) 12 % 13 %<br />
Time required following sometimes/<br />
for a 10% increase participation often (3-4) 35 % 37 %<br />
in the number of in company never/<br />
employees in days 23 22 further rarely (1-2) 54 % 50 %<br />
F-test (sign.) 0.797 education<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.848<br />
Variation of the<br />
number of employees Low degree<br />
throughout the year in % 45 % 41 % of loyalty very often (5) 10 % 7 %<br />
F-test (sign.) 0.379 sometimes/<br />
often (3-4) 33 % 38 %<br />
never/rarely<br />
Problems with the workforce (1-2) 57 % 56 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.629<br />
Lack of very often (5) 29 % 26 %<br />
availability sometimes/ High wage very often (5) 6 % 8 %<br />
of poorly qualified often (3-4) 46 % 47 % demands sometimes/<br />
workers never/ often (3-4) 43 % 40 %<br />
rarely (1-2) 25 % 27 % never/<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.899 rarely (1-2) 51 % 52 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.754<br />
Lack of very often (5) 25 % 19 %<br />
availability of sometimes/ High level of very often (5) 7 % 7 %<br />
qualified workers often (3-4) 50 % 54 % absenteeism sometimes/<br />
never/rarely 26 % 27 % often (3-4) 27 % 21 %<br />
(1-2) never/rarely (1-2) 66 % 71 %<br />
X 2 -test (sign.) 0.579 X 2 -test (sign.) 0.649<br />
n = 114 n = 102<br />
Source: own calculation, company survey 2008<br />
panies rarely locate their more valuable functions<br />
in China, rather tending to do so in their<br />
native countries or in Hong Kong.<br />
Labour turnover as an indicator for numerical<br />
flexibility: The empirical data produced an average<br />
fluctuation rate of 36 % which roughly<br />
concurs with the values fo<strong>und</strong> in the relevant<br />
literature for China. Compared with reference<br />
values from Germany, this figure is very high.<br />
The German Federal Employment Agency<br />
(2010) quotes a figure of 15 % in 2009 for the<br />
manufacturing industry in Germany. This confirms<br />
that the labour market in the Pearl River<br />
Delta is indeed characterised by a high rate of<br />
turnover. Whether this is a result of the shortage<br />
of workers on the supply side and a high<br />
labour turnover rate due to differences in<br />
wages, or whether it is to do with the demand<br />
side because of a high degree of uncertainty regarding<br />
job security, cannot be answered at this<br />
stage, but will be addressed again later using<br />
the results of the regression analysis.<br />
The fluctuation rate in foreign companies is significantly<br />
higher than in Chinese companies<br />
(Tab. 2). This is also in line with the results of<br />
previous studies (PUN/SMITH 2007) and <strong>und</strong>erlines<br />
the reliability of the survey data. This discrepancy<br />
is primarily a result of the extremely<br />
high rate of fluctuation in Taiwanese companies<br />
(52 %) which display a significantly different<br />
result from other foreign companies. This constitutes<br />
a preliminary indication that foreign<br />
companies, and particularly Taiwanese companies,<br />
are obviously unable to compensate for<br />
the disadvantage in wage levels through additional<br />
social welfare benefits or qualification
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 67<br />
measures: Chinese workers apparently react<br />
primarily to monetary incentives, while traditional<br />
forms of social welfare benefits, especially<br />
company residential homes, are no longer<br />
perceived as being attractive.<br />
The level of employee numbers also varies<br />
considerably and, seen over the course of the<br />
entire year, is situated within a corridor of variation<br />
which is, on average, 43 % of the average<br />
number of employees wide. A large proportion<br />
of production in the electronics industry is seasonal<br />
business, since a significant share of<br />
sales turnover in the industrial countries occurs<br />
during the Christmas period. There is no significant<br />
difference between Chinese and foreign<br />
firms in this regard. Larger companies<br />
with more than 500 employees can absorb<br />
these fluctuations better; their volatility, at<br />
34 %, is significantly smaller than for companies<br />
with fewer than 100 employees, which arrive<br />
at a value of 54 %. The electronics companies<br />
in the Pearl River Delta generally have<br />
the ability to adapt very quickly to fluctuations<br />
in demand. For a 10 % increase in the number<br />
of employees, they require an average of only<br />
23 days.<br />
A further indicator for workplace quality and<br />
flexibility is provided by the frequency with<br />
which companies report having problems with<br />
the workforce (Tab. 2). The most common<br />
problem mentioned was the shortage of poorly<br />
qualified workers, which was more frequently<br />
spoken about than the problem of acquiring<br />
qualified workers. This confirms the shortage<br />
of all labour resources in the region. Chinese<br />
companies are slightly more frequently confronted<br />
with these two problems, but the difference<br />
is not significant. The third most frequent<br />
problem mentioned by companies was<br />
job change following participation in a further<br />
education programme. This <strong>und</strong>erlines the considerable<br />
readiness to change one’s job based<br />
on wage discrepancies, especially when newly<br />
acquired qualifications open up possibilities to<br />
receive higher wages. The question of whether<br />
there is truly a positive statistical connection<br />
between qualification measures and fluctuation<br />
which ‘punishes’ those companies which invest<br />
in further education will be addressed at a<br />
subsequent point in the investigation.<br />
Employee perspective<br />
As the presented results demonstrate, the<br />
labour turnover discussed from the company<br />
perspective does not affect all employees in the<br />
same manner. First, the sample of 566 migrant<br />
workers surveyed must be described: 52 %<br />
originate from Henan, Hebei and Hunan, three<br />
inland provinces of China, where the minimum<br />
wage is approximately one-third lower than in<br />
Dongguan (CLB 2008). This considerable<br />
wage gap between the regions of origin and occupation<br />
illustrates the attractiveness of the<br />
Delta as a destination for vocational migrants.<br />
57 % of the migrant workers are female, and<br />
only 28 % are married, which is not surprising<br />
considering the low average age (23.8 years).<br />
These figures all roughly correspond to those<br />
fo<strong>und</strong> in other studies on migrant workers in<br />
Shenzhen (e.g. WANG/WU 2010). The qualification<br />
level of the workers surveyed is also<br />
similar to that fo<strong>und</strong> in the company survey;<br />
the majority (53 %) had completed an intermediate<br />
school education.<br />
A comparison of the two data catchment areas<br />
reveals the following differences: Older, male<br />
and married workers are significantly more frequently<br />
fo<strong>und</strong> in the inner city district than in<br />
the newly developed peri-urban area, as are<br />
those employed as salaried workers. The workers<br />
in the peri-urban industrial area, who are<br />
2.5 years younger on average, have more frequently<br />
held a larger number of jobs in the<br />
past, and their current employment relationship<br />
has existed for seven months fewer than that of<br />
those in the inner city industry district. The<br />
peri-urban industrial area thus tends to employ<br />
a younger and also more mobile worker generation<br />
than the inner city industry district 138.<br />
This result may indeed extend the discussion<br />
on the new generation of workers in terms of<br />
their preferred working location (PUN/LU 2010;<br />
YUE et al. 2010).<br />
Flexibility and company benefits: In approximately<br />
two-thirds of cases (66 %), there is a<br />
fixed written contract between employees and<br />
companies, although contracts are often concluded<br />
for a period of only one year (Fig. 1, linshi<br />
zhigong). Long-term employees only received<br />
a contract with the passing of the revised<br />
version of the employment contracts law<br />
(2008), even though they had mostly already<br />
worked for several years in the same company.<br />
47 % of the sample participants were aware of<br />
the new employment contracts law. Their opinion<br />
of it varied in roughly equal numbers between<br />
scepticism regarding the implementation<br />
at the company level and enthusiasm due to the
68 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 3: Selected employee characteristics<br />
Variables Characteristic Frequency Distribution across industrial χ 2 (sig.)<br />
features areas (%)<br />
Inner city Peri-urban<br />
Occupation* Industrial workers 367 50 50 0.110<br />
(n=444) Salaried employees 77 60 40<br />
Gender Male 243 66 34 0.001<br />
(n=565) Female 322 44 56<br />
Family status Married 160 63 37 0.060<br />
(n=564) Unmarried 404 50 50<br />
Age up to 18 81 42 58 0.001<br />
(n=555) 19 to 24 296 50 50<br />
25 to 29 81 54 46<br />
30 and older 97 72 27<br />
Education Max. intermediate 316 55 45 0.550<br />
(n=561) school qualification**<br />
Above intermediate<br />
school qualification 245 52 48<br />
* analogous to blue-/white collar workers;<br />
** analogous to the Chinese chu zhong, nine compulsory years of schooling<br />
Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />
promise of the eagerly awaited regulation and<br />
strengthened social security. At any rate, the<br />
contracts seemed to provide no effective barrier<br />
concerning numerical flexibility at the time<br />
of the survey, i.e. the rapid entry to and exit<br />
from an employment relationship.<br />
The wage level was fo<strong>und</strong> to be lower than in<br />
the company survey; in both survey areas and<br />
occupational groups, it was reported to be<br />
aro<strong>und</strong> 1,140 Yuan. For this payment, however,<br />
the inner city employees work fewer hours<br />
than those in the peri-urban district (on average<br />
9.6 vs. 9.8 hours/day; with 4.7 vs. 4.0 free<br />
days/month). The conventional assumption,<br />
that a higher level of education and a higher<br />
age are honoured with higher wages was fo<strong>und</strong><br />
to be applicable to this sample as well. Furthermore,<br />
long-term employees earned significantly<br />
more than those employed for a short<br />
period (r = 0.54). A very small, but also significant<br />
correlation (r = 0.13) exists between the<br />
number of previous jobs and the entry wage<br />
level (margin of error of 0.01% in each case).<br />
The wages were reported to be paid punctually<br />
in 80 % of cases.<br />
The industrial conflicts and strikes covered in<br />
other studies (e.g. PUN/LU 2010; SMITH 2006)<br />
are not reflected in these data. However, the<br />
wages do vary depending on the company’s order<br />
situation. The level of monthly wages fluctuates<br />
between the minimum and maximum<br />
figure with an average difference of aro<strong>und</strong><br />
550 Yuan, i.e. approximately half of the average<br />
wage level. In only 18 of 566 cases is the<br />
wage level constant from the beginning. For<br />
65 % of workers, the average wage is above<br />
their starting wage level; 19 % actually earned<br />
more at the beginning of their employment relationship<br />
than their current monthly average.<br />
An explanation for this could be, that in times<br />
of high sales demand, workers are attracted by<br />
offering higher effective wages, which are then<br />
reduced in times of low demand to the level of<br />
the minimum wage. In this manner, company<br />
flexibility externalises market-related uncertainties<br />
by transferring them to workers. The<br />
determinants and fluctuations of the effective<br />
monthly wage will be revisited in the course of<br />
the discussion on reasons for job change.<br />
The spectrum of company benefits (Fig. 2) is<br />
mostly filled with accommodation and meal solutions,<br />
with transport and childcare being a rare<br />
occurrence. In more than 50 % of cases, health
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 69<br />
Fig. 2: Company benefits<br />
Insurance<br />
Meals<br />
Further education<br />
n = 566<br />
Accomodation<br />
Ventilation<br />
During overtime<br />
Breakfast<br />
Dinner<br />
Lunch<br />
Equipment<br />
Gloves<br />
Work clothing<br />
Protection masks<br />
Goggles<br />
Insurance<br />
Accident insurance<br />
Health insurance<br />
Unemployment insurance<br />
Pension<br />
Other social welfare benefits<br />
Technical training<br />
Vocational training<br />
Other qualifications<br />
Other<br />
Goods for day-to-day use<br />
Transport<br />
Childcare<br />
Other provisions<br />
Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />
25<br />
23<br />
5<br />
23<br />
60<br />
103<br />
82<br />
12<br />
80<br />
106<br />
153<br />
150<br />
127<br />
16<br />
70<br />
242<br />
241<br />
239<br />
187<br />
176<br />
97<br />
246<br />
259<br />
316<br />
274<br />
and accident insurance is offered, and 35 % and<br />
40 % of cases involve offers of company-supported<br />
retirement schemes and unemployment<br />
insurance respectively – a figure which could<br />
conceivably have been much lower.<br />
Further education measures are in place in<br />
aro<strong>und</strong> 40 % of cases - a high figure considering<br />
the expectation that unqualified workers<br />
would generally receive no training. Moreover,<br />
training for industrial workers is similarly<br />
common to that for salaried employees. This<br />
49<br />
62<br />
49<br />
336<br />
80<br />
46<br />
73<br />
106<br />
46<br />
66<br />
348<br />
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%<br />
97<br />
142<br />
253<br />
110<br />
263<br />
238<br />
free of charge must be paid for not available<br />
132<br />
276<br />
273<br />
286<br />
179<br />
247<br />
216<br />
251<br />
45<br />
228<br />
206<br />
176<br />
195<br />
190<br />
199<br />
98<br />
106<br />
includes all categories imaginable, from initial<br />
training to further education programmes,<br />
which must be more subtly differentiated for a<br />
more in-depth interpretation.<br />
79 % of those surveyed were living in residential<br />
homes provided by the company, with a<br />
similarly high proportion receiving meals from<br />
the company canteen. As was the case with<br />
wages though, both figures lie beneath those<br />
resulting from the company survey, but both<br />
reveal the same tendency. A dominant charac-<br />
70<br />
81<br />
62<br />
23<br />
28<br />
23<br />
18
70 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Fig. 3: Evaluation of workplace quality by employees<br />
Wage level<br />
Meals<br />
Accommodation*<br />
Reliability of payment<br />
Free time<br />
General satisfaction<br />
Relationship with superiors<br />
Industrial safety<br />
Relationship with colleagues<br />
n = 566<br />
58<br />
60<br />
86<br />
Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />
130<br />
129<br />
137<br />
147<br />
196<br />
teristic of the Chinese manufacturing sector is<br />
the integration of living and working on the<br />
company site. It is disputable, however, to<br />
what extent accommodation and meals may<br />
truly be seen as social welfare benefits. Here,<br />
one must not only consider the above-mentioned<br />
function of these services as an instrument<br />
of control over the workforce, but also<br />
the fact that meals, work clothing and accommodation<br />
all quite frequently require payment<br />
on the part of workers, as well as goods for daily<br />
use, although salaried workers do pay meal<br />
costs themselves significantly more frequently<br />
(0.05) than industrial workers. Over and above<br />
the question of payment, company benefits also<br />
partly serve as a system of occupational<br />
control over workers, an aspect which is dealt<br />
with in detail in studies on the so-called dormitory<br />
labour system (cf. LEE 2005, 17; PUN/<br />
SMITH 2007).<br />
The facilities provided at the company site may<br />
also be counted among company benefits in the<br />
wider sense. An employee of a Japanese company<br />
spoke of table tennis tables, karaoke machines,<br />
free internet access and television.<br />
Courts with basketball hoops are very often to<br />
be fo<strong>und</strong>, although their use could only be documented<br />
in one case; the supposed sport field<br />
342<br />
380<br />
382<br />
386<br />
326<br />
288<br />
339<br />
316<br />
286<br />
161<br />
98<br />
104<br />
70<br />
81<br />
95<br />
66<br />
35<br />
52<br />
34<br />
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%<br />
satisfactory acceptable unsatisfactory<br />
seemed to be used more for the purposes of assemblies.<br />
This leisure programme, as is the<br />
case with other free benefits, can be interpreted<br />
as an incentive measure, although the former<br />
certainly seems to be aimed at the<br />
younger, more mobile generation of workers.<br />
The company benefits differ between the two<br />
data catchment areas in that meals and uniforms<br />
are more often free of charge for workers<br />
in the peri-urban industrial area than in the<br />
inner-city district, the former being significant<br />
(0.01). This possibly constitutes an attempt to<br />
compensate for the peri-urban location and the<br />
lack of alternative accommodation.<br />
Evaluation of workplace quality and priorities<br />
of employees: Workplace quality was investigated<br />
using nine of the categories fo<strong>und</strong> to be<br />
relevant in a preliminary study (Fig. 3). In the<br />
case of wage levels, the absolute proportion of<br />
unsatisfied workers is the highest, and is also<br />
proportionally greater than that of satisfied<br />
workers (18 % to 11 %). When one takes into<br />
account the wage fluctuations presented earlier,<br />
this is hardly surprising. Furthermore, the<br />
quality of meals was the second most common<br />
question to be answered with ‘unsatisfied’<br />
(19 % unsatisfied to 11 % satisfied). Considering<br />
the fact that many employees receive their
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 71<br />
Fig. 4: Subjective priorities for selected aspects of the workplace<br />
Workplace cleanliness<br />
Harmonic working environment<br />
Opportunities for advancement<br />
Flexibility of job entry and exit<br />
Participation in decision-making processes<br />
n = 566<br />
Workplace safety<br />
Training possibilities<br />
Planning security<br />
Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />
entire nutrition from the company canteen, it<br />
indeed seems plausible that low quality of<br />
meals could be a further important determinant<br />
for labour turnover, particularly in the case of<br />
physically exhausting work. This theory, however,<br />
would have to be qualified using a<br />
weighting of various problem areas by the employees.<br />
The employees surveyed appeared to be most<br />
frequently satisfied with the company climate<br />
among colleagues. Safety at the workplace – in<br />
contrast to blatantly negative media reports –<br />
took second place. The relationship to superiors<br />
was evaluated slightly more conservatively,<br />
but nevertheless very positively. The safety<br />
standards at the workplace were either very<br />
high, or the survey participants had experienced<br />
a comparatively poorer conditions previously.<br />
In the inner-city industrial district, respondents<br />
reported significantly more frequently being<br />
unsatisfied with wage levels (0.01) and accommodation<br />
(0.06) than in the peri-urban district.<br />
In the interpretation of these evaluations, one<br />
must take into account which characteristics of<br />
the workplace are indeed important (Fig. 4).<br />
The previously mentioned security aspect and<br />
cleanliness are of immense importance for<br />
workers. The third most important aspect is<br />
training possibilities, and the fifth is opportuni-<br />
461<br />
408<br />
388<br />
385<br />
318<br />
246<br />
243<br />
205<br />
179<br />
187<br />
239<br />
150<br />
103<br />
109<br />
118<br />
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90%100%<br />
very important important not important no opinion<br />
ties for advancement, a sign that even – or perhaps<br />
especially – the unqualified industrial<br />
workers would at least ideally like to realise<br />
the ambition of a career. The participation in<br />
decision-making processes was most rarely reported<br />
to be very important, although a right to<br />
participate would possibly be considered to be<br />
more important now following the recent increase<br />
in public reporting. This all indicates in<br />
which areas an adaptable management could<br />
act to reduce a labour turnover rate which is<br />
clearly too high.<br />
Effects of workplace quality on labour<br />
turnover<br />
Determinants of the turnover rate at the company<br />
level<br />
The conceptional preliminary discussion revealed<br />
a connection between the flexibility of<br />
employment and company success. Positive effects<br />
of this flexibility are particularly due to<br />
the ability to adapt to fluctuations in the market.<br />
Negative effects arise from the loss of<br />
knowledge and abilities through frequent job<br />
changes. It is thus worthwhile to conduct an<br />
analysis of the indicator of this turnover rate<br />
and its explanation in a multiple regression<br />
model with regard to workplace quality and<br />
flexibilisation. Workplace quality and flexibilisation<br />
are operationalised using the indicators<br />
63
72 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 4: Descriptive statistics for the variables of the regression model<br />
n Min Max Mean Standard Explanation<br />
deviation<br />
Dependent variable<br />
Turnover rate 200 0 100 36.08 31.74 Employees leaving the company as a<br />
percentage of the total number of<br />
employees<br />
ln (Turnover rate) 200 0 4,61 3.06 1.20 Natural logarithm of the turnover rate<br />
Workforce-related<br />
variables<br />
Monthly wage 216 600 3,000 1,270 423.39 in Yuan<br />
Number of social<br />
welfare benefits 222 1 5 3.71 1.12 Number<br />
Training for new<br />
employees 222 1 5 4.05 1.05 Intensity of formal and informal<br />
education<br />
Further education 222 0 5 2.53 1.43 Intensity of internal and external<br />
further education<br />
Problems with employees 221 1 5 2.86 0.94 Average frequency of six problems<br />
Employees with tertiary<br />
education 212 0 100 32.26 30.65 as a percentage of the total number of<br />
employees<br />
Flexibility-related variables<br />
10 % increase in the<br />
number of employees 209 1 100 22.80 21.96 Duration in days<br />
Fluctuation of the<br />
number of employees 195 0 100 42.96 27.33 Spread of the number of employees<br />
as a percentage of the average<br />
number of employees<br />
Turnover percentage of<br />
industrial countries 211 0 100 27.76 37.93 as a percentage of total turnover<br />
Number of employees 213 1 3 1.91 0.78 1:-1-99, 2: 100-499, 3: 500 and<br />
above<br />
Source: own calculation, company survey 2008<br />
introduced above. An overview of the variables<br />
of the model can be fo<strong>und</strong> in Tab. 4.<br />
For several dimensions, average values were<br />
created from various component indicators: In<br />
the group of independent variables, one can<br />
thus find the number of social welfare benefits<br />
offered, an education index for formal education<br />
(double weighting) and training of new<br />
employees (simple weighting), a further education<br />
index for internal (simple) and external<br />
(double) further education programmes offered<br />
and a problem index (average value) of the frequency<br />
of the six problems with workers.<br />
In addition to the indicators of flexibilisation<br />
already mentioned, the importance of industrial<br />
countries as a key market (as a percentage of<br />
total sales turnover) and the number of employees<br />
are included in the model. The natural<br />
logarithm of the labour turnover rate is used as<br />
a dependent variable, since exponential rather<br />
than linear relationships were fo<strong>und</strong> between<br />
many variables during the data exploration. An<br />
investigation of the correlation coefficients between<br />
the independent variables showed that<br />
these are generally uncorrelated with each other.<br />
Only two coefficients are above 0.3. The<br />
highest coefficient of 0.352 is attained by the<br />
training and further education indices.<br />
For the explanation of the turnover rate, three<br />
multiple regression models were calculated in<br />
which a differentiation was made between<br />
labour resource-related and flexibility-related<br />
variables. The intention here is to pursue the
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 73<br />
Tab. 5: Determinants of the labour turnover rate using a multiple regression model<br />
Independent variables All variables Workforce-related Flexibility-related<br />
variables variables<br />
stand. stand stand<br />
beta sign. beta sign. beta sign.<br />
Monthly wage -0.135 0.073* -0.136 0.060*<br />
Number of social welfare<br />
benefits 0.112 0.121 0.106 0.128<br />
Training for new employees 0.148 0.049** 0.150 0.042**<br />
Further education -0.030 0.699 -0.033 0.648<br />
Problems with workers 0.175 0.015*** 0.197 0.004***<br />
Employees with tertiary<br />
education -0.226 0.005*** -0.238 0.001***<br />
10 % increase in the<br />
number of employees 0.114 0.107 0.188 0.010**<br />
Fluctuation of the number<br />
of employees 0.158 0.029** 0.158 0.036**<br />
Turnover share of industrial<br />
countries 0.234 0.001*** 0.269 0.000***<br />
Number of employees -0.116 0.140 -0.014 0.858<br />
(constant) 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000***<br />
Dependent variable ln (Turnover rate) ln (Turnover rate) ln (Turnover rate)<br />
R² 0.300 0.179 0.138<br />
corrected R² 0.254 0.152 0.118<br />
F-Test (sign.) 0.000 0.000 0.000<br />
Number of observations 164 192 171<br />
Significance levels: *** p < 1%, ** p < 5%, * p < 10%<br />
Source: own calculation, company survey 2008<br />
question arising from the conceptual section of<br />
whether labour turnover is caused more by a<br />
surplus of demand for workers and job change<br />
stemming from this, or whether it is more a result<br />
of flexible production methods and the<br />
short-term employment relationships connected<br />
to this. The summarised results of the regression<br />
analysis (Tab. 5) show that the labour<br />
resource-related variables possess a slightly<br />
higher explanation power than those related to<br />
flexibility. Altogether, however, the results<br />
point to the fact that both factors exert an influence<br />
on labour turnover, as indeed was expected.<br />
The explanation power of the complete<br />
model is, at 25.4 %, acceptable for survey data.<br />
The following individual results are particularly<br />
noteworthy against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of the<br />
current situation in the Pearl River Delta.<br />
Among the labour resource-related variables, a<br />
higher average monthly wage reduces labour<br />
turnover, as is to be expected. More surprising<br />
is the fact that employees with a tertiary education<br />
(university or polytechnic) change jobs<br />
less frequently than poorly qualified workers.<br />
Generally, one could have assumed that more<br />
highly qualified workers have a wider range of<br />
employment options. But because of the general<br />
shortage of workers, it seems to be actually<br />
poorly qualified workers in the Pearl River<br />
Delta who react to minimal differences in<br />
wages by changing jobs.
74 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
The most interesting results are those for training<br />
and further education as well as social welfare<br />
benefits. The more comprehensive a training<br />
or education programme offered to new<br />
employees is, the higher the labour turnover<br />
rate. Workers obviously exploit the additional<br />
qualification gained to receive higher wages at<br />
other companies. Further education does not<br />
reduce fluctuation either, indeed having no significant<br />
influence. Social welfare benefits also<br />
prove not to be a substitute for higher wages.<br />
Their influence on labour turnover is positive,<br />
but not significant. This result rather confirms<br />
that the total provision of services for employees<br />
based on the notion of control is indeed becoming<br />
less attractive for the younger generation<br />
of migrant workers.<br />
Among the flexibility-related variables, the<br />
marketing orientation of companies towards<br />
industrial countries possesses the greatest explanation<br />
power. The standardised beta coefficient<br />
is also higher than that of every individual<br />
workforce-related variable. The integration<br />
into global value chains thus seems to demand<br />
a particularly high degree of short-notice adaptation<br />
ability from electronics firms in the Pearl<br />
River Delta, which have a direct effect on<br />
labour turnover. Companies whose employee<br />
numbers fluctuate more strongly during the<br />
year because of seasonal influences naturally<br />
have a higher rate of labour turnover. Despite<br />
the significant differences in the turnover rate<br />
between Chinese and foreign firms (Tab. 2),<br />
these differences disappear in the regression<br />
model when other independent variables are<br />
used (Tab. 5). An additional model calculated<br />
with an owner dummy did not lead to an improvement<br />
of the explanation power or to a significant<br />
influence of the dummy.<br />
In summary, the results of the regression analysis<br />
lead to the conclusion that wage levels are<br />
the principal tool for companies when it comes<br />
to establishing a stable stock of workers. Social<br />
welfare benefits designed to exercise control<br />
over workers and qualification initiatives, on<br />
the other hand, lead to a higher rate of labour<br />
turnover, and are thus not worthwhile for the<br />
company that carries the costs for these measures.<br />
Since companies with more highly qualified<br />
workers are less vulnerable to high labour<br />
turnover rates, a freeloader pattern of behaviour,<br />
in which other companies or the state<br />
f<strong>und</strong> the qualification of workers, is probably<br />
the most successful strategy in the short term.<br />
In the case of one-sided orientation towards<br />
global markets, which have proven to be particularly<br />
susceptible to strong fluctuations in<br />
demand, a diversification into the Asian or local<br />
market seems to have a balancing effect.<br />
These preliminary explanation attempts will be<br />
elaborated upon in the continued course of the<br />
research project along with findings on the<br />
connection between jobs and job changes from<br />
the employee perspective.<br />
Workplace-related job change and mobile<br />
workers<br />
Job change and worker characteristics: The<br />
duration of employment and the number of<br />
previous jobs held are indicators for the mobility<br />
or ‘readiness to change’ of workers. 17 % of<br />
those sampled reported an employment period<br />
of up to two months. This figure must be<br />
viewed in connection with the date of the survey<br />
(22/23 March), which is shortly after the<br />
spring festival (7-10 February), since the<br />
spring festival is a time which often sees significant<br />
job changes. Altogether, 51 % of the<br />
workers had been working for the same company<br />
for a maximum of six months, while only<br />
8 % had been doing so for more than three<br />
years. It is noticeable that the average duration<br />
of employment was longer in the inner-city district<br />
than in the peri-urban district (18.9 vs.<br />
11.2 months) – a discrepancy which is intensified<br />
by the higher average age.<br />
At first glance, the number of jobs has a positive<br />
connection with age, as was expected<br />
(Tab. 6). Among the relatively young workforce<br />
– only 17 % are older than 29 years – the<br />
number of previous jobs held varies in a nonlinear<br />
fashion between the age groups: the 19-<br />
24 age group reported more frequently a larger<br />
number of previous jobs than the 25-29 age<br />
group. Although the average age in the innercity<br />
district is significantly higher, the workers<br />
there reported that they had a similar number<br />
of previous jobs (1.5 in the inner-city district<br />
vs. 1.6 in the peri-urban district). The mobility<br />
of the younger workers is thus generally<br />
greater. The group of more highly qualified<br />
workers was also fo<strong>und</strong> to have a larger number<br />
of previous jobs than those with a lower education<br />
level (Tab. 6), although one must take<br />
into account the fact that education reforms<br />
have led to a generally higher standard of education<br />
for younger workers, and that the shortage<br />
of workers has only been beneficial for<br />
worker mobility since 2004.
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 75<br />
Tab. 6: Number of previous jobs, differentiated according to age and education level<br />
Previous jobs (%) absolute<br />
0 1 2 >3 numbers<br />
Age<br />
up to 18 71 17 11 1 76<br />
19-24 66 20 11 3 284<br />
25-29 51 30 13 5 76<br />
30 and older 68 20 7 5 93<br />
Total<br />
Education level*<br />
Maximum of an intermediate school<br />
65 21 10 4 529<br />
qualification<br />
Minimum of a secondary school<br />
68 19 10 3 300<br />
qualification 61 23 11 5 235<br />
Total 65 20 10 4 535<br />
*The differences between the two groups are weakly significant on the basis of the Chi²-Test (6 % margin of error).<br />
Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />
With these results, however, one must take into<br />
account the job market-related conditions in<br />
the Pearl River Delta. An increased shortage of<br />
workers has emerged there since 2004. This has<br />
led to a situation in which younger workers<br />
have a wider range of jobs to choose from,<br />
which is a very desirable development from the<br />
point of view of employees. From the perspective<br />
of the companies affected, a high turnover<br />
rate must be considered problematic, particularly<br />
in the case of more highly qualified workers,<br />
since it creates a tendency for more knowledge<br />
to be lost and, in some cases, for greater financial<br />
investment in further education which eventually<br />
proves to be useless for the employer.<br />
Reasons for changing jobs: The company survey<br />
suggests a connection between labour<br />
turnover and wages as well as education level;<br />
secondary data also indicate a surplus of vacant<br />
jobs. In addition, the employee survey provides<br />
reasons for changing jobs on the part of the<br />
workers themselves (Tab. 7). These are related<br />
to workplace quality and flexible company organisation,<br />
but are also partly linked to the residency<br />
status of the workers.<br />
The most common reason for employees to<br />
change jobs was fo<strong>und</strong> to be fluctuation of effective<br />
monthly wages. The second most common<br />
reason was poor hygiene at the workplace<br />
(23 %), with the third being a return to one’s<br />
home region for the period of the Chinese New<br />
Year festival (18 %). This is not surprising for a<br />
number of reasons, but particularly because the<br />
number of vacation days was not contractually<br />
regulated in the private sector until the introduction<br />
of the employment contracts law. Each<br />
worker was entitled to only three days during<br />
the period of the New Year festival, which, in<br />
most cases, was not even enough to cover the<br />
travel time to the workers’ home regions. Most<br />
employees thus consider their employment relationship<br />
to be terminated automatically once<br />
the number of vacation days is exceeded. The<br />
official end of a contract or the acquisition of<br />
another job through friends or relatives were<br />
named less frequently as reasons for a change<br />
of jobs (7 % and 8 % respectively).<br />
The answer frequencies differ between the two<br />
investigation areas only in the point ‘ending of<br />
the contract’, which was named much more<br />
frequently in the inner-city district as a reason<br />
for changing jobs than in the peri-urban district<br />
(10 vs. 43 mentions). More highly qualified<br />
workers responded similarly to poorly qualified<br />
workers. As expected, employees in a<br />
salaried position most rarely named workplace<br />
hygiene (16 %) as the reason for their last job<br />
change. More interesting is the distinction between<br />
men, who much more frequently cited<br />
low wages and workplace hygiene (151 and 90<br />
mentions respectively), and women (128 and<br />
78 mentions). Women, however, much more<br />
frequently cited the journey home for the<br />
spring festival as a reason for the change in<br />
jobs (86 vs. 41 mentions). Of all the age-
76 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 7: Reasons for changing one’s previous job<br />
Job change due to … (multiple answers) Frequency Percentage Percentage of cases<br />
low wages 280 39 54<br />
poor workplace hygiene (noise, smell, 170 23 33<br />
light, temperature)<br />
end of the employment relationship because of trip<br />
home for the spring festival 127 18 25<br />
acquisition of a new job through friends or relatives 56 8 11<br />
end of the contract 53 7 10<br />
other reasons 40 5 8<br />
Total number of answers 726 100 141<br />
Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />
groups surveyed, furthermore, those over the<br />
age of 30 most frequently gave low wages as a<br />
reason (45 %). This group is obviously the<br />
least ready to accept wage disadvantages; its<br />
members probably more frequently have to<br />
support a family with their income than<br />
younger, single workers.<br />
Conclusion and policy<br />
recommendations<br />
The presentation and contrasting of the empirical<br />
results prove that the electronics industry<br />
in the Pearl River Delta is indeed characterised<br />
by a high degree of labour turnover: It could be<br />
confirmed, firstly, that flexibility in the sense<br />
described by ATKINSON (1984) is a means of organising<br />
companies, which is particularly<br />
made use of by companies embedded in global<br />
value chains. Secondly, workplace-related<br />
characteristics of labour turnover, employee<br />
characteristics and personal reasons for job<br />
change were fo<strong>und</strong> to be important determinants.<br />
Altogether, the two influencing factors<br />
were fo<strong>und</strong> to be of similar importance.<br />
In the area of workplace quality, wage levels<br />
were fo<strong>und</strong> to be the central criterion for<br />
changing jobs. Due to low wages, which are,<br />
on average, well above the legal minimum<br />
wage, but subject to very severe fluctuations,<br />
workers in the lower-income sector react to<br />
even a small difference in wages by changing<br />
employers. The shortage of workers, which is<br />
identified as a central problem by companies,<br />
intensifies this situation. Company benefits do<br />
not offer any significant incentive to remain at<br />
a firm for longer periods of time either - here,<br />
accommodation and meals are most commonly<br />
provided, although meals in particular are very<br />
frequently deemed to be insufficient by employees.<br />
The qualification initiatives offered at the<br />
workplace in the form of training and further<br />
education, which are of importance with regard<br />
to labour turnover and for technological upgrading<br />
processes of companies, possibly also<br />
contribute to a further increase of labour<br />
turnover at the company level. Education level<br />
and low age increase the probability of job<br />
change at the individual level. This connection<br />
seems to be due mostly to the high degree of<br />
sensitivity of workers to wage differences and<br />
the size of the labour market coupled with the<br />
simultaneous shortage of workers. Since it is<br />
not worthwhile in such a situation for an individual<br />
company to provide qualification measures,<br />
an explanation must also be fo<strong>und</strong> here<br />
for the low frequency with which training and<br />
further education programmes are offered. The<br />
empirical investigation provided evidence to<br />
suggest that in the electronics industry of the<br />
Pearl River Delta, a qualification lock-in indeed<br />
exists in the area of labour-intensive and<br />
wage-sensitive production. Frequent job<br />
changes and few possibilities for further qualification<br />
strengthen each other reciprocally,<br />
since workers change employers both in seeking<br />
higher wages and because of the opportunity<br />
achieve this more effectively following the<br />
attaining of a qualification.<br />
In summary, three b<strong>und</strong>les of causes, all connected<br />
with one another, could be fo<strong>und</strong> for<br />
worker shortage and a high rate of labour<br />
turnover:
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 77<br />
– company influences, shaped by a company<br />
organisation system aiming for numerical<br />
and financial flexibility and reacting to the<br />
necessities of being embedded in global value<br />
chains;<br />
– assessment of the workplace quality determined<br />
by individual characteristics of the<br />
workers (lower age groups, education level,<br />
gender) and their subjective priorities and<br />
evaluations (stage of life, promotion orientation,<br />
family support payments), and<br />
– regional influences shaped by the dynamic,<br />
globalised development of the Pearl River<br />
Delta and its socio-demographic transformation<br />
(internal migration led by migrant<br />
workers), which were not explicit subjects of<br />
this investigation, but are nevertheless important<br />
for the interpretation of the results.<br />
One of the decisive questions for the maintenance<br />
of competitiveness in the region through<br />
upgrading processes is that of how the high<br />
labour turnover rate can be generally reduced<br />
and more smoothly organised for both companies<br />
and workers, and how the significance and<br />
value of qualification can be increased at the<br />
same time. Several state-subsidised flagship<br />
companies have, without doubt, already been<br />
successful in producing considerable technological<br />
innovation (KROLL/SCHILLER 2010),<br />
without the large number of small and medium-sized<br />
companies being able to keep up with<br />
this development. One possibility to change<br />
this lies in the strengthened use of intermediates<br />
on the job market, which are beginning to<br />
appear in the form of a private sector-organised<br />
employment agency and temporary labour<br />
agency branch (XUE et al. 2010). During the<br />
preliminary selection of potential employees,<br />
the organisation of security collateral and the<br />
provision of social welfare benefits, these<br />
agencies could make a mediation contribution<br />
and could also take on responsibilities in the<br />
area of qualification. Over and above this, a<br />
progressing regulation of work at all education<br />
levels would be profitable for both the employee<br />
as well as the employer side of the equation<br />
by increasing the continuity of employment relationships.<br />
This, however, would be a development<br />
which would tend to move away from<br />
the concept of a flexible firm, and which may<br />
not be possible for firms to implement due to<br />
the rapid adaptation required within the global<br />
value chain. Flexibility and upgrading, howev-<br />
er, are connected in an interdependent relationship.<br />
Only a strategic reorientation of companies<br />
towards long-term-focused business models<br />
will be able to lead to appropriately large<br />
investment being made in education and employee<br />
binding, with numerical flexibility no<br />
longer being used as the only option for adapting<br />
to global market fluctuations.<br />
In the case of education and qualification, due<br />
to its character as a public resource, state institutions<br />
are also obliged to a certain degree to<br />
provide or support appropriate programmes.<br />
Here, at the district level, this would be a starting<br />
point for cooperation between companies<br />
and education institutions in the form of regional<br />
qualification alliances. As part of a research<br />
project currently in progress, for example,<br />
a cooperation between ThyssenKrupp in<br />
Zhongshan and a local public further education<br />
institution is being investigated (interview<br />
10.4. 2010). Here, basic questions pertaining to<br />
the organisation of the Chinese education system<br />
are addressed which go beyond the scope<br />
of this paper. The attractiveness of the working<br />
and living environment (“soft location factors”)<br />
are also increasingly moving into the focus<br />
of the second generation of migrant workers,<br />
and particularly of more highly qualified<br />
workers.<br />
The empirical results of the research project<br />
form an image of the specific situation of the<br />
electronics industry in the Pearl River Delta at<br />
the time of the survey. Further research is necessary<br />
in several areas, especially concerning<br />
the importance and organisation of internal and<br />
external company further education, in the<br />
course of which the perspective of companies<br />
should be connected with that of employees.<br />
From the point of view of companies, a more<br />
exact investigation of the effects of labour<br />
turnover and qualification on upgrading<br />
processes and company success would be interesting.<br />
From the point of view of employees,<br />
a focus on more highly qualified workers in the<br />
core workforce would provide a valuable<br />
knowledge supplement. In addition, external<br />
providers of training and further education<br />
should be included as a target group in an investigation.<br />
Acknowledgement<br />
The authors would like to thank two anonymous reviewers<br />
for their helpful comments on an earlier version<br />
of this paper and Kerry Jago for the translation of the
78 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
original manuscript. The empirical research used in this<br />
paper was carried out within the Priority Programme<br />
(SPP) 1233 “Megacities – Megachallenge: The Informal<br />
Dynamics of Global Change” f<strong>und</strong>ed by the German<br />
Research Fo<strong>und</strong>ation (DFG), whose support is<br />
thankfully acknowledged.<br />
References<br />
ALBRECHT, S. (2002). Regionale Arbeitsmärkte <strong>und</strong> Flexibilisierungsprozesse.<br />
Geographische Zeitschrift,<br />
(90)3-4, 180-193.<br />
ALBRECHT, S. (2005). Flexibilisierung der Arbeit: Prozesse<br />
<strong>und</strong> Strategien aus geographischer Sicht. Koblenz.<br />
(Koblenzer Geographisches Kolloquium, 27).<br />
ATKINSON, J. (1984): Manpower strategies for flexible<br />
organizations. In: Personnel management, 16, 28-31.<br />
BRANDT, O. (2009): Lokalisiertes Lernen oder funktionale<br />
Spezialisierung – wie nachhaltig gelingt die Integration<br />
von gering Qualifizierten in den regionalen Arbeitsmarkt?<br />
Antworten aus Niedersachsen. Hannover.<br />
(Diss.)<br />
CHAN, K.W. (2010a): A China paradox. Migrant labor<br />
shortage amidst rural labor supply ab<strong>und</strong>ance. In:<br />
Eurasian Geography and Economics, (51)4, 513-531.<br />
CHAN, K.W. (2010b): The global financial crisis and migrant<br />
workers in China. ‘There is no future as a labourer;<br />
returning to the village has no meaning’. In: International<br />
Journal of Urban and Regional Research, (34)3,<br />
659-678.<br />
CLB (China Labour Watch)(2008): Minimum monthly<br />
wage standards in selected provinces/ municipalities/cities<br />
in China. Internet: http://www. chinalaborwatch.org/2006<br />
Editorials/07-24-2006 Minimum Wage<br />
Chart.htm, 18.10. 2010.<br />
COHEN, W.M./LEVINTHAL, D. (1990): Absorptive capacity:<br />
a new perspective on learning and innovation. In:<br />
Administrative Science Quarterly. 35, 128-152.<br />
ENRIGHT, M./SCOTT, E./CHANG, K. (2005): Regional<br />
powerhouse. The Greater Pearl River Delta and the rise<br />
of China. Singapore.<br />
ERNST, D./NAUGHTON, B. (2008): China’s emerging industrial<br />
economy. Insights from the IT industry. In: Mc-<br />
Nally, C. (Ed.): China’s emergent political economy.<br />
Capitalism in the dragon’s lair. Abingdon, 39-59.<br />
FAN, C. C. (2008): China on the move. Migration, the<br />
state, and the household. London. (Reprint: Routledge<br />
studies in human geography, 21).<br />
GDSTATS (Statistics Bureau of Guangdong Province)<br />
(2010): Guangzhou statistical yearbook 2010. Internet:<br />
http://www.gdstats. gov.cn/tjnj/ml_e.htm, 20.2. 2011.<br />
GEFFKEN, R./MA, D./HSIE, S.-M. (2010): Das chinesische<br />
Arbeitsvertragsgesetz. Hamburg.<br />
GERLACH, K./MEYER, W./TSERTSVADZE, G. (2002): Entwicklung<br />
der qualifikatorischen Segregation im Verarbeitenden<br />
Gewerbe. In: Bellmann, L./Kölling, A.<br />
(Hrsg.): Betrieblicher Wandel <strong>und</strong> Fachkräftebedarf.<br />
Nürnberg, 51-84.<br />
German Federal Employment Agency (B<strong>und</strong>esagentur<br />
<strong>für</strong> Arbeit) (2010): Arbeitsmarkt 2009. Nürnberg. (Amtliche<br />
Nachrichten der B<strong>und</strong>esagentur <strong>für</strong> Arbeit 58,2).<br />
HE, G. (2006): The shortage of peasant workers in the<br />
Pearl River Delta Region. An Explanation based on Todaro<br />
migration model. In: Asian Social Science, (2)12,<br />
41-52.<br />
HEBEL, J./SCHUCHER, G. (2006): Flexibility and security<br />
in China’s emerging ‘Socialist’ market labour regime.<br />
In: Baur, M. / Gransow, B. / Jin, Y. / Shi, G. (Eds.): Labour<br />
mobility in urban China. An integrated labour market<br />
in the making? Berlin, 19-49. (Berliner China-Studien,<br />
46)<br />
HKTDC (Hong Kong Trade Development Council)(2010):<br />
Mounting price pressure on China exports.<br />
Research Report. Hong Kong.<br />
HÜRTGEN, S./ LÜTHJE, B./SCHUMM, W./SPROLL, M.<br />
(2009): Von Silicon Valley nach Shenzhen. Globale Produktion<br />
<strong>und</strong> Arbeit in der IT-Industrie. Hamburg.<br />
JIANG, B./BAKER, R./FRAZIER, G.V. (2009): An analysis<br />
of job dissatisfaction and turnover to reduce global supply<br />
chain risk. Evidence from China. In: Journal of Operations<br />
Management, 27, 169-184.<br />
KILIAN, P./BEISSWENGER, S./XUE, D. (2010): Floating or<br />
settling down? Migrant workers and mega-urban development<br />
in the Pearl River Delta, China. In: Geographische<br />
R<strong>und</strong>schau - International Edition, (6)2, 50-56.<br />
KIM, L. (1997): Imitation to Innovation. Dynamics of<br />
Korea’s technological learning. Boston, MA.<br />
KNIGHT, J.B./DENG, Q./LI, S. (2011). The puzzle of migrant<br />
labour shortage and rural labour surplus in China.<br />
In: China Economic Review (forthcoming).<br />
KROLL, H./SCHILLER, D. (2010): Establishing an interface<br />
between public sector applied research and the Chinese<br />
enterprise sector: Preparing for 2020. In: Technovation,<br />
(30)2, 117-129.<br />
LEE, C.K. (2005): Livelihood struggles and market reform.<br />
(Un)making Chinese labour after state socialism.<br />
Geneva. (ILO Occasional Paper).<br />
LEWIS, W.A. (1954): Economic development with unlimited<br />
supplies of labour. In: The Manchester School,<br />
(22)2, 139-191.<br />
LÜTHJE, B. (2008): Arbeitspolitik in der chinesischen<br />
IT-Industrie. Neue Perspektiven in der Diskussion um<br />
internationale Arbeitsstandards. Frankfurt am Main.<br />
(<strong>Institut</strong> <strong>für</strong> Sozialforschung: Studie im Auftrag der<br />
Hans-Böckler-Stiftung).<br />
MEYER, S./SCHILLER, D./REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2009): The<br />
Janus-faced economy. Hong Kong firms as intermediaries<br />
between global customers and local producers in<br />
the electronics Industry. In: Tijdschrift voor Economische<br />
en Sociale Geografie, (100)2, 224-235.<br />
MEYER, S./SCHILLER, D./REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2012): The<br />
localization of electronics manufacturing in the Greater<br />
Pearl River Delta, China. Do global implants put down<br />
local roots? In: Applied Geography, 32, 119-129.<br />
PUN, N. (2005): Made in China. Subject, power and resistance<br />
among women workers in a global workplace.<br />
Durham.<br />
PUN, N./SMITH, C.J. (2007): Putting transnational labour<br />
process in its place. The dormitory labour regime in<br />
post-socialist China. In: Work Employment Society,<br />
(21)1, 27-45.
Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 79<br />
PUN, N./ LU, H. (2010): Unfinished proletarianization.<br />
Self, anger, and class action among the second generation<br />
of peasant-workers in present-day China. In: Modern<br />
China, (36)5, 493-519.<br />
REILLY, P.A. (1998): Balancing flexibility. Meeting the<br />
interests of employer and employee. In: European Journal<br />
of Work and organizational Psychology, (7)1, 7-22.<br />
STAIGER, B. (Hrsg.)(2008): Das große China-Lexikon.<br />
Geschichte, Geographie, Gesellschaft, Politik, Wirtschaft,<br />
Bildung, Wissenschaft, Kultur. Darmstadt.<br />
SCHILLER, D. (2011): The role of foreign and domestic<br />
firms in regional innovation systems of latecomer countries.<br />
Empirical evidence from the electronics industry<br />
in the Pearl River Delta. Erdk<strong>und</strong>e, (65)1, 25-42.<br />
SHEN, J. (2007): Labour disputes and their resolution in<br />
China. Oxford.<br />
SMITH, T. (Hg.) (2006): Challenging the chip. Labor<br />
rights and environmental justice in the global electronics<br />
industry. Philadelphia.<br />
STURGEON, T. (2002): Modular production networks. A<br />
new American model of industrial organization. In: Industrial<br />
and Corporate Change, (11)3, 451-496.<br />
The Economist (2010): The next China. As the supply of<br />
migrant labour dwindles, the workshop of the world is<br />
embarking on a migration of its own. In: The Economist,<br />
29.7. 2010. Internet: http://www.economist.com/<br />
node/16693397, 12.9. 2010).<br />
TSERTSVADZE, G. (2005): Qualifikatorische Segregation.<br />
Entwicklung <strong>und</strong> Bestimmungsgründe. Eine theoretische<br />
<strong>und</strong> empirische Analyse. Aachen.<br />
VALVERDE, M./TREGAKIS, O. (2000): Labor flexibility<br />
and firm performance. In: International Advances in<br />
Economic Research, (6)4, 649-661.<br />
WANG, M.Y./WU, J. (2010): Migrant workers in the urban<br />
labour market of Shenzhen, China. In: Environment<br />
and Planning A 42. (forthcoming).<br />
WHITELEY, A./CHEUNG, S./QUAN, Z.S. (2000): Human<br />
resource strategies in China. Singapore.<br />
XUE, D./LIN, T./KRAAS, F./KILIAN, P. (2010): Informal<br />
job-seeking agencies and their role in the ‘World Factory’<br />
of the Pearl River Delta. A case study in Tangxia<br />
Township, Dongguan City, Guangdong Province. In:<br />
Geographical Research, (29)10, 1793-1801. (Chinese<br />
with an English summary).<br />
YANG, D.L. (2005): China’s looming labor shortage. In:<br />
Far Eastern Economic Review, (168)2, 19-24.<br />
YUE, Z./LI, S./FELDMAN, M.W./DU, H. (2010). Floating<br />
choices. A generational perspective on intentions of rural<br />
urban migrants in China. In: Environment and Planning,A42,<br />
545-562.<br />
YU, H./HUANG, Y. (2009): Impact of the global economic<br />
crisis on the Pearl River Delta and the Yangtze<br />
River Delta. Singapore. (East Asian <strong>Institut</strong>e Backgro<strong>und</strong><br />
Brief No. 477, National University of Singapore).<br />
YU, H./ZHANG, Y. (2009): New initiatives for industrial<br />
upgrading in the Pearl River Delta. Singapore. (East<br />
Asian <strong>Institut</strong>e Backgro<strong>und</strong> Brief No. 464, National<br />
University of Singapore).
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 80-96<br />
Wenying Fu, Guangzhou (China)/ Daniel Schiller/ Javier Revilla Diez, Hannover<br />
Strategies of using social proximity and organizational proximity<br />
in product innovation<br />
Empirical insight from the Pearl River Delta, China<br />
Abstract: In this paper we investigate how the innovation behavior of firms to capitalize on social<br />
proximity with independent firms and organizational proximity with parent companies and<br />
foreign customers contributes to innovation in the Pearl River Delta (PRD), China. While traditional<br />
views often hold that Chinese firms rely heavily on organizational proximity with parent<br />
companies and foreign customers to gain access to knowledge, we aim for insights into whether<br />
localized learning mechanisms based on informal social relations have emerged in the region after<br />
more than thirty years of industrialization. Based on a questionnaire survey of 359 innovative<br />
electronics firms, this paper demonstrates that firms which use social proximity to foster innovation<br />
are emerging in the PRD, and that it is mainly applied by domestic firms as a ‘spying device’<br />
to catch up with the latest technology and market preference in order to trigger new product ideas.<br />
Nevertheless, the achievements of product innovation performance made by applying social proximity<br />
in interactive learning are fairly small, which <strong>und</strong>erpins the instability of the trust-based interactive<br />
learning between firms in the region. The results of the paper provide insight into the development<br />
stage of the regional innovation system in the Pearl River Delta, calling upon an effective<br />
governance infrastructure to be put in place to stabilize interactive learning on the local<br />
scale.<br />
Keywords: social proximity, organizational proximity, guanxi, product innovation<br />
Introduction<br />
Since the opening policy was introduced in<br />
1978, China has seized the opportunity of the<br />
global industrial shift, and some areas along<br />
the eastern coast have experienced dramatic<br />
economic growth. The Pearl River Delta,<br />
which is located on the south-east coast of the<br />
Guangdong province, has developed into one<br />
of the biggest production sites for computers<br />
and electronics due to its advantage of low-cost<br />
and flexible production. The electronics industry<br />
in this region is very export-oriented. The<br />
region manufactures over 50 % of the world’s<br />
desktop computers and 40 % of PC components,<br />
such as PC heads, PC cases and other<br />
semi-manufactured products (see http://www.<br />
gdiid. gd. gov.cn/gdiid /billion /lay2-3.htm).<br />
Moreover, many domestic brands in the Pearl<br />
River Delta have rapidly developed and taken<br />
a considerable share of the global market. The<br />
literature on the regional industrial develop-<br />
ment in latecomer countries such as China emphasizes<br />
the role of multinational enterprises<br />
and the global production network, which they<br />
have organized in the regions (DICKEN, 1976;<br />
DOLLAR, 2005; MORRISON et al., 2008; YEUNG,<br />
2009). In the initial industrializing process<br />
which took place in the Pearl River Delta, it is<br />
indisputable that technology transfer and learning<br />
relied heavily on global lead firms. The low<br />
absorptive capacity of the young local firms in<br />
the Pearl River Delta led to the limited size and<br />
variety of knowledge and expertise on the local<br />
scale, which, as a whole, hindered the interactive<br />
learning among the firms and hence the<br />
opportunities to benefit from each other’s ideas<br />
and skills. Due to the limited expertise and<br />
know-how in the initial industrialization phase,<br />
firms had no opportunity to implement active<br />
innovation and upgrading strategies. Moreover,<br />
the ab<strong>und</strong>ance of cheap land and labor<br />
left no incentives to initiate risky innovation<br />
activities. However, the high-speed growth,
Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 81<br />
driven by foreign direct investment (FDI), has<br />
gradually exhausted the cheap land and labor<br />
in the Pearl River Delta, and has been greatly<br />
constrained by both internal and external factors<br />
in recent years. On the one hand, the high<br />
inflation rate, which leads to the continual<br />
pressure of rising costs, is gradually eroding<br />
the competitive edge in low-cost production.<br />
On the other hand, the export firms are faced<br />
with more trade obstacles in the developed<br />
market due to the protection of the local employment<br />
market after the financial crisis.<br />
Firms either have to meet the high standards of<br />
safety and quality in order to maintain the market<br />
share in developed countries, or they have<br />
to exploit the new market opportunities in the<br />
domestic economy. Against this backgro<strong>und</strong>,<br />
innovation and upgrading are high on the agenda<br />
of both firms and the government. Furthermore,<br />
conditions for interactive learning and<br />
systemic innovation have developed, with the<br />
electronics firms in the Pearl River Delta having<br />
accumulated a certain amount of knowledge<br />
after thirty years of processing operations<br />
and having diversified into numerous product<br />
niches in the electronics industry. It is therefore<br />
important, at this point, to investigate whether<br />
firms are capable of exploiting and commercializing<br />
the knowledge stock through reciprocal<br />
interactive learning. The raising of this<br />
question corresponds to the literature on regional<br />
competitiveness which emerged in the<br />
1990s arguing that the enduring competitiveness<br />
of regions lies in the socialized embedded<br />
process of knowledge production, exploitation<br />
and dissemination.<br />
In the following it is attempted to approach this<br />
question using the concept of proximity. As<br />
MASSARD/MEHIER (2009) suggest, it provides a<br />
conceptually more so<strong>und</strong> measurement of accessibility<br />
than the concept of the externality<br />
of simply being there. Other than physical distance,<br />
relational space based on rules, contracts<br />
and informal social interaction has been taken<br />
into comprehensive consideration. By assessing<br />
the strategies and capability of firms to<br />
capitalize on social proximity via informal<br />
guanxi-networks to foster innovation, rather<br />
than on organizational proximity with parent<br />
companies or foreign customers, insights into<br />
the evolving production system in the Pearl<br />
River Delta from a platform driven by foreign<br />
direct investments to a regional innovation system<br />
are expected during the course of this investigation.<br />
The use of social relations is a strategic move<br />
by firms to achieve trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
among independent business partners. ZHOU et<br />
al. (2003) demonstrate that firms in the Pearl<br />
River Delta have to maintain intensive interpersonal<br />
interaction with customers due to the<br />
unreliable institutional system. Moreover, informal<br />
and continual interaction among various<br />
economic players, embedded in guanxinetworks,<br />
is an important method of doing<br />
business in Chinese society (LOVETT et al.<br />
1999). Rather than simply applying informal<br />
practice in flexible production to save transaction<br />
costs and thus react quickly to market<br />
needs (NORTH 1990; MEYER et al. 2009), the<br />
capacity to capitalize further on informal social<br />
relations in order to generate and foster innovation<br />
outcome is critical for the emergence of<br />
a regional innovation system in the Pearl River<br />
Delta. However, this localized learning process<br />
based on social assets does not take place automatically<br />
and is <strong>und</strong>er constant pressure of<br />
destruction. Information sharing can be reduced<br />
or biased, as each seeks to gain the most<br />
at the other’s expense, especially for uncertain<br />
and risky innovation activities (CHESBROUGH/<br />
TEECE 1996). The formation and stabilization<br />
of interactive learning in the business sector<br />
depends on market conditions and should be<br />
strengthened by public initiatives and supporting<br />
infrastructure (HEIDENREICH 2004). By<br />
identifying strategic firm behavior of using<br />
proximities to foster innovation, we want to<br />
contribute to the <strong>und</strong>erstanding of the innovation<br />
activities in the Chinese context and shed<br />
light on the direction of policy initiatives to<br />
strengthen the interactive learning activities in<br />
the business sector of the electronics industry<br />
in the Pearl River Delta.<br />
It should be noted that this paper does not intend<br />
to explore exclusively the role of the five proximities,<br />
i.e. geographical proximity, cognitive<br />
proximity, organizational proximity, social proximity<br />
and institutional proximity, as defined by<br />
BOSCHMA (2005). Instead, it focuses on organizational<br />
and social proximity, which are deemed<br />
to be most relevant to the previous discussion of<br />
regional development in the context of latecomer<br />
countries. Moreover, these two forms of proximity<br />
may be addressed by conscious firm<br />
strategies and can thus be achieved through the<br />
efforts of individual firms. In addition, the effect<br />
of geographical and cognitive proximity is controlled<br />
to a certain degree by placing the focus of<br />
the empirical investigation on firms belonging
82 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
to the same electronics sector and co-locating in<br />
the same mega-urban region in China.<br />
Organizational and social proximity in<br />
innovation – the Chinese context<br />
The concept of proximity developed in the<br />
1990s by the French School contributes to the<br />
<strong>und</strong>erstanding of the mechanisms behind the<br />
interactive process of knowledge transfer (KI-<br />
RAT/LUNG 1999; TORRE/GILLY 2000; TORRE/<br />
RALLETT 2005; BOSCHMA 2005; MENZEL<br />
2008). Proximity is a concept that is usually<br />
discussed with innovation, since it plays an<br />
important role in promoting the trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
when <strong>und</strong>ertaking complex and<br />
highly risky innovation activities. Proximity<br />
carries a plural sense. It goes beyond geographical<br />
proximity, which has a limited role<br />
without the support of other proximities. With<br />
respect to firm strategies in the Chinese context,<br />
firms can, on the one hand, rely on organizationally<br />
proximate partners, such as parent<br />
companies and foreign customers, to gain information,<br />
ideas and supported knowledge<br />
which transcend the limits of geographical<br />
proximity. On the other hand, firms can also<br />
establish trust-based social networks with geographically<br />
proximate independent business<br />
partners, such as domestic customers, univer-<br />
Fig. 1: Knowledge transfer across firm<br />
bo<strong>und</strong>aries<br />
Source: own draft<br />
sities, research institutes and market agencies,<br />
seeking information and knowledge within social<br />
proximity. How information and knowledge<br />
are transferred across firm bo<strong>und</strong>aries to<br />
support the complex innovation process is<br />
shown in Fig. 1. The knowledge transfer organized<br />
within social and organizational proximity<br />
facilitates communication and strengthens<br />
cooperation owing to <strong>und</strong>erstanding and trust<br />
within the proximity bo<strong>und</strong>ary.<br />
Organizational proximity<br />
Organizational proximity refers to the sharing<br />
of reference space and knowledge that is<br />
strengthened by hierarchy and control within<br />
the same organization, such as firm, group and<br />
cooperation networks (BOSCHMA 2005). With<br />
the development of information, communication<br />
and transportation technology, simple colocation<br />
is no longer a necessary determinant<br />
for knowledge transfer. Networks, which even<br />
transcend the bo<strong>und</strong>ary of countries, begin to<br />
play a role as vehicles of knowledge diffusion.<br />
In the third wave of globalization in the 1980s,<br />
the bulk of foreign capital flowed to developing<br />
countries in the form of direct investment<br />
in manufacturing (DOLLAR 2005). Meanwhile,<br />
forms of network coordination involving a<br />
large number of participants have taken the<br />
place of integrated organizational bo<strong>und</strong>aries<br />
at transnational corporations, which ERNST<br />
(2005) specifically described as a “global flagship<br />
network”. This network links the flagship’s<br />
own subsidiaries, affiliates and joint<br />
ventures with its subcontractors, suppliers and<br />
service providers, as well as with partners in<br />
strategic alliances (ERNST 2005, 91).<br />
In order to reduce costs and stay flexible towards<br />
market demands, the flagship organizations,<br />
including the brand firms, contract manufacturers,<br />
first-tier suppliers and large trade<br />
companies, strengthen the core competencies<br />
and, at the same time, outsource volume manufacturing<br />
and other functions along the globally-organized,<br />
networked value chain (ERNST/<br />
KIM 2002). Three factors determine the methods,<br />
that these flagship organizations apply<br />
in order to govern the network (GEREFFI et al.<br />
2005): the complexity of transactions, the ability<br />
to codify knowledge and the capabilities of<br />
the supply base.<br />
New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics relates transaction<br />
cost to the institutional environment<br />
(NORTH 1990). When the rules are not guaran-
Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 83<br />
teed by formal institutions such as laws and<br />
regulations, organizational proximity appears<br />
as a reasonable governance mode to curb the<br />
opportunist behavior of business partners, such<br />
as distorting business information, failing to<br />
fulfill commitments or malicious imitation<br />
(HENNART 1993). As a result of incomplete institutional<br />
protection, most of the firms in the<br />
developing countries conduct innovation ‘inhouse’<br />
instead of licensing and assigning contractual<br />
arrangements to unaffiliated firms<br />
(SCHMITZ 1995; SCHMITZ/NADVI 1999). For the<br />
global flagship that organizes production in developing<br />
countries, organizational proximity is<br />
not only conducive to reducing opportunist risk<br />
related to physical and human capital investment,<br />
but also enables the efficient downward<br />
transfer of knowledge, especially the tacit<br />
knowledge owing to the path-dependent nature<br />
of firm routine development (NELSON/WINTER<br />
1982) towards the suppliers and subcontractors<br />
with <strong>und</strong>erdeveloped technological and managerial<br />
capabilities.<br />
Accordingly, organizational proximity provides<br />
two advantages for firms in latecomer<br />
countries. It provides them with access to<br />
knowledge, especially tacit knowledge in the<br />
advanced technological field. The flagship typically<br />
provides the organizationally proximate<br />
subsidiaries, suppliers and subcontractors with<br />
machinery, blueprints, production and quality<br />
control manuals, product and service specification<br />
and training handouts. YEUNG (2009)<br />
states the importance of external network<br />
building in acquiring capabilities in the Asian<br />
context and introduces a concept called “strategic<br />
coupling” to <strong>und</strong>erstand better the evolution<br />
of local and regional firms in their dynamic<br />
articulation in the global production network.<br />
MORRISON et al. (2008) also show that<br />
firms gain technological capabilities from participating<br />
in global value chains. Not only that,<br />
firms in latecomer countries also join the international<br />
production network in order to acquire<br />
tacit knowledge, which is necessary to absorb<br />
and exploit the encoded knowledge, by having<br />
the engineers and managers from foreign partners<br />
train on site. Furthermore, IVARSSON/<br />
ALVSTAM (2005) demonstrate that geographical<br />
proximity with foreign transnational corporations<br />
is crucial for local suppliers to absorb external<br />
technology through regular and ongoing<br />
interaction with their primary foreign customers.<br />
It is possible that the suppliers upgrade and coevolve<br />
with the buyer when the technological<br />
and organizational change enables a more sophisticated<br />
supply chain (YEUNG 2009). In<br />
2004, Lenovo bought the PC operation from<br />
IBM and upgraded from an original equipment<br />
manufacturer (OEM) to an own brand manufacturer<br />
(OBM). In 2004, TCL (Shenzhen) coestablished<br />
a mobile phone joint venture with<br />
Alcatel. In 2007, China Electronic Cooperation<br />
subsidiary Sungfei (Shenzhen) acquired<br />
the mobile phone operation from Phillips.<br />
These are examples of upgrading by enhancing<br />
internal absorptive capacity and strategically<br />
recognizing the coupling chances with global<br />
lead firms. However, organizational proximity<br />
alone has a limited role in upgrading and innovation.<br />
Firstly, many brand owners arrange the<br />
global strategic layout in such a way that<br />
strategic research and development (R&D),<br />
marketing and management are located in their<br />
home countries or in regions in developed<br />
countries where innovation partners and reliable<br />
institutions are available (FEINBERG/GUP-<br />
TA 2004), while functions such as production,<br />
sales and logistics are located in developing<br />
countries (PAN/CHI 1999). Although the internationalization<br />
of R&D activities has grown<br />
significantly since the 1990s (OECD 1998),<br />
technology and knowledge to which domestic<br />
firms have access is still limited and mostly<br />
low-end. Secondly, global buyers tend to promote<br />
incremental product and process upgrading<br />
and oppose upgrading if this creates opportunities<br />
for suppliers to acquire a broader range<br />
of customers (HUMPHREY 2004). Consequently,<br />
the global buyers and traders might be bypassed<br />
by suppliers if the latter gain the ability<br />
to work directly with brand companies in developed<br />
countries.<br />
In the electronics industry, there is a trend of<br />
applying fewer hierarchy relations in the global<br />
chain governance mode. Maturing technology<br />
such as module production that enables the<br />
codifying of knowledge is one of the factors<br />
behind this trend. Moreover, as long as local<br />
firms establish core competences that ensure<br />
the reciprocity of knowledge sharing, it is quite<br />
possible that they are able to capitalize on the<br />
use of social proximity to exploit knowledge<br />
and foster innovation. Social proximity can<br />
thereby be used as a complementary strategy in<br />
fostering innovation in order to overcome the<br />
shortcomings of organizational proximity.
84 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Social proximity<br />
Social proximity relates to trust and commitment<br />
based on kinship, friendship and cooperation<br />
experience (BOSCHMA 2005). It is secured<br />
through informal daily face-to-face interaction<br />
such as meeting, chatting, eating together and<br />
joint entertainment. Trust and commitment are<br />
gradually established in the social interaction<br />
process, which contributes to interactive learning<br />
and cooperation. Social networks are not<br />
spatially bo<strong>und</strong>, but can be sustained and produced<br />
by the ongoing collective interaction of<br />
players located close to each other (BOSCHMA<br />
2005).<br />
Social proximity does not only foster the communication<br />
of tacit knowledge which is difficult<br />
to trade in the market, but also reduces opportunist<br />
behavior through the establishment of<br />
durable relations. Social ties and relations<br />
thereby have an influence on economic outcomes<br />
(GRANOVETTER 1985). Guanxi, as an<br />
informal way of doing business in China, has<br />
received growing attention in the recent organizational<br />
literature (PARK/LUO 2001; RAMA-<br />
SAMY et al. 2006; ZHANG/ZHANG 2006). Similar<br />
to the concept of social proximity, guanxi<br />
refers to informal interpersonal relationships<br />
and exchanges of favors for the purpose of doing<br />
business in traditional Chinese society<br />
(LOVETT et al. 1999). PENG (2003) points out<br />
that the reciprocal and utilitarian types of<br />
guanxi are becoming more important than the<br />
obligatory type in times of institutional transition.<br />
In reciprocal guanxi between friends and<br />
colleagues in particular, the implicit rule of<br />
‘paying back favors’ (Chinese: renqing), due to<br />
the fear of damaging one’s social reputation<br />
and prestige, actually strengthens the constant<br />
social interaction through the idea of exchanging<br />
favors. In the Chinese business world today,<br />
guanxi plays an important role in facilitating<br />
economic exchanges and overcoming administrative<br />
costs in the face of a deficient<br />
institutional framework (PARK/LUO 2001),<br />
such as when starting the business, concluding<br />
contracts, acquiring institutional protection and<br />
responding flexibly to changing demands.<br />
However, its role in innovation has not yet<br />
been analyzed.<br />
The changing role of guanxi, i.e. the Chinese<br />
way of establishing and maintaining social<br />
proximity, in business performance has important<br />
implications for the dynamic regional<br />
competitiveness. The socially and territorially<br />
embedded, collectively interactive learning<br />
process is becoming a prominent feature of<br />
competitive industrial clusters even in a globalized<br />
era (MASKELL 1998; ASHEIM/ISAKSEN<br />
2002). The approach of regional innovation<br />
systems assumes that the localized assets and<br />
processes are the primary source of the innovation<br />
capabilities of the firms. (COOKE et al.<br />
1997; DOLOREUX/PARTO 2005). In a well-functioning<br />
regional innovation system, the local<br />
firms are capable of capitalizing on social<br />
proximity not only to facilitate effective<br />
knowledge transfer, but also to generate innovation<br />
outcomes. However, the prerequisite for<br />
this is that firms are willing and able to apply<br />
social proximity to foster innovation. If clustering<br />
firms all compete fiercely in identical<br />
standardized products, the regional knowledge<br />
base becomes low-level and homogeneous.<br />
Firms are often reluctant to share knowledge<br />
because the imitation cost is low and reciprocity<br />
of interaction is marginal. In this case, social<br />
proximity, such as that between customers<br />
and suppliers, can only be used as a way of sustaining<br />
a flexible and responsive production<br />
system. As a result, the role of social proximity<br />
in fostering innovation is limited, which<br />
leads to rather loose local innovation networks.<br />
When firms are willing to <strong>und</strong>ertake interactive<br />
learning and share knowledge with each other,<br />
guanxi helps in curbing the risk of opportunism<br />
related to innovation, which is specifically defined<br />
by STANDIFIRD/MARSHALL (2000) as the<br />
risks of asset specificity, behavioral uncertainty<br />
and environmental uncertainty. First of all,<br />
guanxi with managers of business partners may<br />
reduce the risk of asset specificity, which refers<br />
to the circumstance in which partners who do<br />
not own and invest specific assets switch suddenly<br />
to other partners in the process of innovation.<br />
Reciprocal guanxi with business partners<br />
is path-dependent to some extent, because<br />
people are less disposed to ruining the precious<br />
guanxi networks for quick profit. Long-term<br />
guanxi acts as a constraint for opportunism,<br />
and this brings mutual trust and assurance for<br />
cooperation. Secondly, guanxi networks with<br />
other partners can reduce the risk of behavioral<br />
uncertainty when sharing knowledge and ideas<br />
with cooperation partners. As an old Chinese<br />
saying goes, ‘you will never be defeated if you<br />
know everything about your opponent’. For<br />
example, if the cooperation partner in innovation<br />
activities wants to steal ideas to develop a<br />
new product ahead of you, and the contracts
Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 85<br />
and legal systems are not able to help or cost<br />
too much, it is safer to know ex ante about the<br />
backgro<strong>und</strong>, reputation and capacity of your<br />
cooperation partner through the guanxi network<br />
from other managers (as intermediaries)<br />
in the industry. Thirdly, guanxi with government<br />
officials can reduce the risk of environmental<br />
uncertainty, as innovation policies are<br />
always unsteady and vague in China. Managers<br />
and entrepreneurs cannot simply rely on government<br />
bulletins as their information channel.<br />
They actually rely more on guanxi when<br />
searching for and confirming information.<br />
They often obtain key information and a detailed<br />
explanation of the policies through<br />
guanxi. Information sorted through guanxi networks<br />
is more reliable and trustworthy, and<br />
thus allows for better informed decisions on investment<br />
in innovation.<br />
However, guanxi networks carry the risk of a<br />
negative lock-in effect. As guanxi networks depend<br />
on the constant exchange of favors, they<br />
are also fragile once the exchange stops. Firms<br />
are locked in with current business partners,<br />
fearing that the destruction of the subtle guanxi<br />
network with a single business partner would<br />
induce the loss of all other partners who are related<br />
to this partner. In this case, firms do not<br />
act as profit-maximizing entities, but rather as<br />
guanxi-satisfying ones. Outdated production<br />
modes and product types might persist and are<br />
harmful for upgrading and innovation (HSU/<br />
SAXENIAN 2000).<br />
Brief summary<br />
For Chinese firms, organizational proximity is<br />
of particular importance. In the early phase of<br />
development, the capability of local firms is<br />
not fully developed due to the weak industrial<br />
base, thus resulting in an ill-functioning<br />
knowledge spillover mechanism on the local<br />
scale. In this phase, hierarchy and control in<br />
the same organizational framework by the foreign<br />
parent company or OEM customer is essential<br />
for organizing production relations, and<br />
this becomes the primary source for local firms<br />
to gain codified and tacit knowledge, mostly in<br />
a passive way. However, organizational proximity<br />
in this phase is not able to trigger innovation<br />
with low-skill assembly operation<br />
aro<strong>und</strong> standardized products among the local<br />
firms.<br />
With the development of the local production<br />
system, local firms have accumulated a certain<br />
level of capability which enables them to absorb<br />
and exploit knowledge. In this case, firms<br />
can either use organizational proximity to seize<br />
the opportunities of value chain upgrading with<br />
the sophistication of the supply chain and technological<br />
diversification, or they can capitalize<br />
on social proximity to form reciprocal innovative<br />
synergy with organizationally distant partners<br />
that have diversified into specific product<br />
lines and market segments. Particularly for<br />
small and medium-sized firms, the collective<br />
learning facilitated by social proximity is essential<br />
for their survival and growth, and is also important<br />
for the development of a self-sustained<br />
local production system (CAPELLO 1999). The<br />
use of organizational and social proximity by<br />
firms is mutually reinforcing. On the one hand,<br />
the ability of local firms to use social proximity<br />
and transform it into innovative synergy and<br />
profit provides a greater incentive for foreign<br />
firms to transfer more advanced technology and<br />
activities to their organizationally proximate<br />
partners in developing countries. Moreover, this<br />
grants the local firms and governments more<br />
bargaining power to negotiate with foreign partners,<br />
which results in more stable manipulation<br />
of strategic coupling. On the other hand, new<br />
information on markets and technology that is<br />
pumped into the local system by firms using organizational<br />
proximity with geographically distant<br />
partners makes local collective learning<br />
more dynamic (BATHELT et al. 2004). This conceptual<br />
process concerning the dynamic interaction<br />
of organizational and social proximity is<br />
illustrated with Fig. 2.<br />
Fig. 2: Dynamism of proximity in regional<br />
development<br />
Source: own draft
86 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Based on the discussion on the role of organizational<br />
proximity and social proximity as a<br />
firm strategy to foster innovation, the following<br />
hypotheses are formulated:<br />
Hypothesis 1: By developing internal capacity<br />
and strategic coupling within the global production<br />
network, it is possible for firms in latecomer<br />
countries to capitalize on organizational<br />
proximity in order to foster innovation and<br />
upgrading. However, firms that rely only on a<br />
vertical hierarchy with global lead firms to<br />
foster innovation have limited potential for upgrading<br />
their position in the value chain.<br />
Hypothesis 2: Most Chinese firms are engaged<br />
in guanxi networks, which are an ongoing<br />
mode of interaction for maintaining social<br />
proximity between business partners. Firms<br />
with limited capabilities and short-term strategies<br />
are only able to capitalize on guanxi for<br />
low-cost and flexible production. On the other<br />
hand, in a mature regional innovation system,<br />
firms are capable of using social proximity to<br />
facilitate the complex interaction in the innovation<br />
process and to foster the innovation<br />
outcomes.<br />
Data and methodology<br />
The electronics industry in the Pearl River<br />
Delta, has been selected as the research area<br />
for this study. The empirical data used to answer<br />
the research question were taken from a<br />
standardized survey of electronics firms in the<br />
Pearl River Delta, Guangdong province, China.<br />
The industrial development in the Guangdong<br />
province is the outcome of a subtle mixture<br />
of global networks, public institutional<br />
framework and unexplored socio-cultural contexts<br />
(BELLANDI/TOMMASO 2005). In this<br />
study, survey data from the firm level are used<br />
to explore the strategies of firms to use social<br />
proximity - i.e. embedded in guanxi networks<br />
between independent business partners - as<br />
well as organizational proximity to global<br />
firms in fostering product innovation. In doing<br />
so, insights are expected to be gained with respect<br />
to the role of ‘global pipelines’ and ‘local<br />
buzz’ that contribute to the innovation dynamics<br />
in this region based on the previous<br />
discussion.<br />
The company survey targeted electronics<br />
firms in four cities in the eastern part of the<br />
Pearl River Delta, where the electronics industry<br />
is dominant (as in Shenzhen and Dongguan)<br />
or developing very quickly (as in<br />
Huizhou and Heyuan). In total, 422 electronics<br />
companies were interviewed during a threemonth<br />
period from September to November<br />
2009. Of the surveyed firms, 359 are <strong>und</strong>ertaking<br />
product innovation activities. These firms<br />
are the analytical basis of this article. Among<br />
these innovating firms, 62 % are domestic<br />
firms and 38 % are wholly foreign-owned<br />
firms or joint ventures. The company survey<br />
was conducted by telephone and post. Questionnaires<br />
were addressed to CEOs or senior<br />
executives of the companies. The telephone<br />
and post method was complemented by a telephone<br />
follow-up aimed at reducing the number<br />
of unanswered questions. The response rate<br />
was 53 %.<br />
Due to a certain amount of missing data, the<br />
sample number in the following analysis is<br />
slightly reduced. The issue of unanswered<br />
questions among the surveyed firms along with<br />
refusals led to the sample selection bias. Firms<br />
that were willing and able to answer the questionnaires<br />
completely usually had a higher level<br />
of human capital or a more formal organizational<br />
routine, which eases the <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
and communication between firms and the universities<br />
conducting the survey. Moreover,<br />
these firms were more interested in the strategic<br />
plan we promised to provide after the survey,<br />
than the firms that refused or left too many<br />
questions unanswered, which reflects their upgrading-oriented<br />
strategy. In fact, this selection<br />
bias controls for the technological level of the<br />
surveyed firms, ensuring that the innovation<br />
activities they <strong>und</strong>ertake are not limited to lowvalue<br />
innovation and thus require more coordination<br />
and learning in the innovation process.<br />
In order to test the hypotheses, typical innovation<br />
behavior that makes use of the two proximities<br />
in the product innovation process was<br />
firstly identified based on the theoretical discussion<br />
(Tab.1). Firms were asked to rank the<br />
importance (on a scale of 1 to 5 with increasing<br />
importance) of interaction with business partners<br />
in different aspects with regard to acquiring<br />
new innovative ideas and obtaining codified<br />
and tacit knowledge. By means of factor<br />
analysis, two dimensions of proximity for the<br />
interaction with different players were identified.<br />
The results clearly show that the firms are<br />
not only acquiring codified knowledge and tac-
Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 87<br />
Tab. 1: Operationalization of analysis on proximity use in product innovation<br />
New product<br />
ideas (NPI)<br />
Obtaining<br />
codified<br />
knowledge<br />
(NPCK)<br />
Obtaining tacit<br />
knowledge<br />
(NPTK)<br />
Interaction<br />
mode<br />
(NPInteraction)<br />
Source: own survey<br />
Internal efforts<br />
From organizationally<br />
proximate partners<br />
From organizationally<br />
distant partners<br />
Internal efforts<br />
From organizationally<br />
proximate partners<br />
From organizationally<br />
distant partners<br />
Active learning<br />
Received from organizationally<br />
proximate partners<br />
Received from organizationally<br />
distant<br />
partners<br />
Informal guanxi<br />
network<br />
Active searching<br />
Remarks Explained<br />
variance<br />
of each<br />
factor<br />
Own development of ideas; selfabsorption<br />
and learning through<br />
license purchasing and reverse<br />
engineering<br />
Interacting with parent companies and<br />
foreign customers<br />
Interacting with domestic customers,<br />
foreign customers, universities, research<br />
institutions and sales agents<br />
Self-purchasing of equipment and<br />
software<br />
Interacting with parent companies and<br />
foreign customers<br />
Interacting with domestic customers<br />
and foreign customers<br />
Sending staff to domestic customers or<br />
leading domestic firms, foreign customers<br />
or leading foreign firms, and<br />
universities for training<br />
Receiving training and know-how<br />
from people sent by parent company<br />
and foreign customers<br />
Receiving training and know-how<br />
from people sent by domestic customers<br />
and foreign customers<br />
Interacting through guanxi, for<br />
example gaining information on the<br />
reputation and capacity of innovation<br />
partners from other business partners,<br />
relatives and friends in the innovation<br />
process<br />
Searching for information on partners<br />
via internet, exhibition and sales<br />
agents in the innovation process<br />
Total<br />
explained<br />
variance<br />
15 % 60 %<br />
12 %<br />
33 %<br />
24 % 85 %<br />
27 %<br />
34 %<br />
44 % 74 %<br />
13 %<br />
17 %<br />
52 % 79 %<br />
27 %
88 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
it knowledge from parent companies and foreign<br />
customers, but that they are also interacting<br />
with external partners beyond the organizational<br />
hierarchy, for example domestic customers,<br />
universities, research institutions and<br />
sales agents, to obtain new ideas and required<br />
knowledge. The organizational proximity<br />
with parent companies and foreign customers<br />
is closer than that with domestic customers<br />
and external institutes in the context of latecomer<br />
countries, as previously discussed. Also,<br />
the social proximity with domestic customers<br />
and external institutes can substitute<br />
for the lack of organizational proximity<br />
among independent firms and organizations to<br />
some degree in order to enhance trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
in the innovation process. Combined<br />
with the general question pertaining to<br />
the use of social relations with all business<br />
partners (interaction mode), insight into the<br />
degree of proximity use in the innovation<br />
process can be secured.<br />
In the empirical test, cluster analysis uses the<br />
items shown in Tab. 1 to identify different patterns<br />
of capitalizing on social and organizational<br />
proximity. In cluster analysis, there is<br />
rarely one single best solution. A good cluster<br />
analysis should firstly use as few clusters as<br />
possible, and secondly capture all statistically<br />
and empirically important clusters. We follow<br />
a four-step procedure to ensure the internal<br />
validity of the clustering result (DELMAR et al.<br />
2003). First, hierarchical clustering with<br />
Ward’s method and squared Euclidean distances<br />
was conducted to assess the possible<br />
clustering results. In this step, we arrived at<br />
two to six cluster solutions and derived each<br />
centroid from each cluster solution. The second<br />
step was to use the centroids derived in<br />
the first step to perform the K-means cluster.<br />
The result of the K-means cluster was compared<br />
with that of the hierarchical cluster using<br />
cross tabulation. A significant level in<br />
Lambda lower than 0.05 is considered to be<br />
able to verify the relative stability of the cluster<br />
results across samples. After running these<br />
two procedures, we settled on three clusters<br />
that are internally stable and easy to interpret<br />
from the perspective of innovation behavior<br />
with respect to the use of proximities.<br />
We applied regression analysis to explore further<br />
the exact relationship of the use of proximities<br />
and product innovation performance<br />
by controlling for firm-specific characteristics<br />
such as size, ownership, age and internal absorptive<br />
capacity. The dependent variable in<br />
the regression model is product innovation performance.<br />
In questionnaire data, especially in<br />
developing countries, it is always difficult to<br />
obtain an exact measurement of new products<br />
that is reliable and comparable. Therefore, we<br />
asked firms to evaluate the degree of improvement<br />
of two aspects of production innovation<br />
performance, i.e. product function expansion<br />
and product categories upgrading (on a scale of<br />
one to five with increasing degrees of improvement).<br />
The dependent variable in the regression<br />
is the average score of these two<br />
items. A shortcoming of this variable is that it<br />
has a bo<strong>und</strong> value of one to five. The problem<br />
here is that it is based on a subjective evaluation,<br />
and that those firms that marked the same<br />
score might not be completely similar in their<br />
achievement. The distribution of the composite<br />
score of innovation performance is shown in<br />
Fig. 3. The censoring of the data set can be<br />
clearly seen, since there are far more cases with<br />
scores of three to five, which is to be expected<br />
in questionnaire answers because the firms all<br />
attempt to make a good impression. With this<br />
particular issue of censored data, ordinaryleast-squares<br />
(OLS) regression provides inconsistent<br />
estimates of the parameters (LONG<br />
1997). Therefore, we applied a Tobit regression<br />
which is unaffected by this issue. The independent<br />
variables are defined in Tab. 2.<br />
Fig. 3: Histogram distribution of product<br />
innovation outcome<br />
Source: own survey
Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 89<br />
Tab. 2: Independent variables in product innovation outcome regression<br />
Firm characteristics<br />
Absorptive capacity<br />
Innovation behavior<br />
1 Specific classification of products into the different levels could be referred to appendix C.<br />
Source: own survey<br />
Empirical results<br />
Use of proximity in innovation: the overall<br />
pattern<br />
The results of the cluster analysis, which differentiates<br />
between three types of innovation<br />
behavior related to the capacity of capitalizing<br />
on social and organizational proximity in the<br />
process of product innovation, are demonstrated<br />
in Tab. 3.<br />
Indicators Description<br />
Defined according to Chinese firm size standard, 1<br />
as large firms with no less 300 million Yuan sales<br />
Size<br />
and no less than 2000 employees, otherwise as<br />
small and medium-sized with the value of 0<br />
Ownership<br />
– Socially embedded innovator: Firms in this<br />
group interact frequently with external partners<br />
in combination with their internal capability.<br />
With regard to obtaining codified and<br />
tacit knowledge in the product innovation<br />
1 as firms with foreign participation (wholly owned<br />
or joint venture), 0 as firms with 100 % domestic<br />
participation<br />
Age Years since establishment of the firm<br />
Level of technical staff<br />
Percentage of technical staff that have bachelor<br />
degree or above multiplied by training frequency<br />
Level of managerial<br />
staff<br />
CEO education<br />
Development capability<br />
Initial product<br />
technology<br />
Behavior of using<br />
different proximities<br />
Percentage of managerial staff that have bachelor<br />
degree or above multiplied by training frequency<br />
1 as CEO below bachelor degree<br />
2 as CEO with bachelor degree<br />
3 as CEO with graduate degree (master or doctor)<br />
4 as CEO with bachelor or above combined with<br />
overseas experience<br />
1 as having product development capability, 0 as<br />
not<br />
Defined according to International Standard Industrial<br />
Classification of all Economic Activities, Rev<br />
31, 1 as producing low-tech products when starting<br />
business, 2 as producing medium-tech products<br />
when starting business; 3 as producing high-tech<br />
products when starting business<br />
Defined by the cluster analysis in the next part; included<br />
in the model as a series of dummy variables.<br />
process, firms of this kind tend to rely more<br />
on customers and use the active strategy of<br />
sending people to business partners for acquiring<br />
tacit knowledge. In the interaction<br />
process with these partners, firms in this category<br />
flexibly combine formal active<br />
searching and informal networks (guanxi<br />
with family members, friends and business<br />
partners) when interacting with partners in<br />
the innovation process. Although it is not<br />
possible to specify exactly which interaction<br />
method is applied by the firms when interacting<br />
with each partner (because the related<br />
matrix would be too complex to be answered<br />
by the firms), it is possible to conclude indirectly<br />
that firms in this group rely on social
90 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 3: Results of cluster analysis*<br />
Socially embedded Organizationally Lame<br />
innovator dependent innovator innovator<br />
NPI_external partner 0.54 0.25 -0.32<br />
NPI_internal 0.52 0.07 -0.31<br />
NPCK_customer 0.60 -0.15 -0.34<br />
NPTK_passive from customer 0.46 0.07 -0.22<br />
NPTK_active learning 0.58 -0.12 -0.35<br />
NPInteraction_informal 0.60 -0.06 -0.33<br />
NPInteraction_formal searching 0.26 -0.01 -0.17<br />
NPI_parent comp. & foreign -0.11 1.01 -0.12<br />
NPCK_parent comp. -0.38 1.96 -0.27<br />
NPCK_self purchase -0.17 0.12 0.10<br />
NPTK_passive from parent comp. -0.47 2.06 -0.16<br />
Number<br />
* Ward’s method/squared Euclidean distance<br />
Source: own survey<br />
104 41 171<br />
proximity to external partners in general during<br />
the process of product innovation to a<br />
greater degree than firms in the other two<br />
clusters. They are actually socially embedded<br />
innovators, and social proximity is not<br />
only used as a way of acquiring codified and<br />
tacit knowledge by interacting with external<br />
partners, but also as a way of triggering new<br />
product ideas, which is a feature of capable<br />
firms in a well-functioning regional innovation<br />
system.<br />
It is worth mentioning that although these<br />
firms are already able to extend the scope of<br />
interactive learning in the innovation process<br />
to capitalize further on social proximity, they<br />
still rely on organizational proximity with<br />
foreign customers to a certain degree in order<br />
to acquire codified and tacit knowledge.<br />
This again supports the mutual reinforcing<br />
effect of social and organizational proximity.<br />
Socially active innovators tend to apply<br />
mixed strategies in using proximity to facilitate<br />
interactive learning.<br />
– Organizationally dependent innovator: In<br />
contrast, organizationally dependent innovators<br />
rely heavily on organizational proximity<br />
to gain access to and absorb knowledge.<br />
They turn to their parent companies to obtain<br />
codified and tacit knowledge in the process<br />
of product innovation, i.e. in a more passive<br />
way due to the hierarchical control. The new<br />
product ideas originate mainly from parent<br />
companies as well as from powerful foreign<br />
customers.<br />
What is again noteworthy is that organizationally<br />
dependent innovators show a certain<br />
tendency to interact with external partners to<br />
prompt product innovation, although to a<br />
lesser degree than socially embedded innovators.<br />
However, the much lower value in informal<br />
interactions indicates that these firms<br />
are not able to capitalize on social proximity<br />
to foster innovation as well as their socially<br />
embedded counterparts. Moreover, their<br />
method of interacting with innovative partners<br />
is not characterized by any particular<br />
feature, which indicates a more passive attitude<br />
towards product innovation compared<br />
to socially embedded innovators.<br />
– Lame innovator: Compared to the previous<br />
two kinds of firms, lame innovators have<br />
low values for all the indicators that are related<br />
to product innovation. Lame innovators<br />
are not actively involved in triggering<br />
new ideas of innovation, nor do they strive to<br />
search for codified and tacit knowledge,<br />
which is important for positive product innovation<br />
outcome. Moreover, they are quite<br />
vague and unsettled in their ways of interacting<br />
with partners in the innovation<br />
process. In short, they are not able to interact<br />
with external players to initiate innovation
Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 91<br />
Tab. 4: Difference in innovation behavior between large firms and small and medium sized<br />
enterprises (SME)<br />
Firm ownership Socially embedded Organizationally Lame innovator Total<br />
innovator dependent innovator<br />
Domestic firms 73 (37 %) 17 (9 %) 105 (54 %) 195<br />
Foreign firms 31 (26 %) 23 (19 %) 66 (55 %) 120<br />
Total<br />
χ<br />
104 (33 %) 40 (13 %) 171 (54 %) 315<br />
2 =9.434, p=0.009<br />
Source: own survey<br />
and do not have the capacity to organize internal<br />
learning.<br />
A look at the number of firms in each cluster<br />
shows that the number of lame innovators exceeds<br />
the sum of socially embedded and organizationally<br />
dependent innovators in our sample.<br />
This is proof of the immature internal absorptive<br />
capacity of most firms in the Pearl<br />
River Delta to benefit from external interaction<br />
in order to trigger innovation. However, the<br />
number of socially embedded innovators is two<br />
times higher than the number of organizationally<br />
dependent innovators. This seems to be an<br />
indication of a maturing regional innovation<br />
system in the Pearl River Delta, where some<br />
local firms are capable of benefiting from localized<br />
knowledge sources by capitalizing on<br />
informal social relations. But it also reflects the<br />
difficulty of most firms in the Pearl River Delta<br />
to ‘couple strategically’ with global firms to<br />
upgrade their position in the value chain. By<br />
studying the relocation issue of Taiwanese personal<br />
computer firms, YANG (2009) also pointed<br />
out that Taiwanese firms in the Pearl River<br />
Delta are less oriented towards the strategic<br />
coupling of local and global knowledge<br />
sources than their counterparts in the Yangtze<br />
River Delta.<br />
Use of proximity in innovation: difference<br />
between domestic and foreign firms<br />
In the interest of a deeper insight into innovation<br />
behavior in terms of proximity use among<br />
the electronics firms in the Pearl River Delta,<br />
investigations of the domestic and foreign<br />
firms were conducted separately. Tab. 4 shows<br />
the distribution of the above-mentioned clustering<br />
groups for domestic and foreign firms.<br />
At first glance, it can be seen that the domestic<br />
and foreign firms do not differ from each other<br />
in the inclination to <strong>und</strong>ertake interactive<br />
learning aiming at fostering product innovation<br />
outcomes. However, the strategies of using<br />
proximity as a way to ensure trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
in interactive learning differ between<br />
these two groups of firms. Domestic firms<br />
tend to interact with other independent business<br />
partners through the use of social proximity<br />
to gain reliable information and support,<br />
while foreign firms resort more to their organizationally<br />
proximate parent companies and<br />
foreign customers to gain access to innovation-related<br />
knowledge.<br />
The different behavior of using proximities in<br />
different processes of product innovation between<br />
domestic and foreign firms is demonstrated<br />
in Fig. 4 more thoroughly. As shown by<br />
the left part of the figure, foreign firms use<br />
much more organizational proximity to foster<br />
innovation, especially in terms of acquiring<br />
new product ideas. The reason for foreign<br />
firms interacting more with their parent companies<br />
and foreign partners to trigger innova-<br />
Fig. 4: Use of proximities for domestic and<br />
foreign firms<br />
Source: own survey
92 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Tab. 5: Tobit regression on innovation outcome<br />
Independent variables (1) Product innovation (2) Product innovation<br />
outcome1 (average score outcome1 (average score<br />
of evaluation) of evaluation)<br />
Constant 3.01*** 2.64***<br />
(0.282) 6 (0.281)<br />
Level of technical staff 0.0006 0.0006<br />
(0.001) (0.001)<br />
Level of managerial staff 0.0008 0.0008<br />
(0.001) (0.001)<br />
CEO education 0.16** 0.16**<br />
(0.065) (0.065)<br />
Development capability 0.52*** 0.52***<br />
(0.188) (0.188)<br />
Medium-tech vs. 0.19 0.19<br />
Initial low-tech2 (0.174) (0.174)<br />
product High-tech vs. 0.54** 0.54**<br />
technology low-tech2 (0.251) (0.251)<br />
Overall effect5 —* —*<br />
Ownership -0.26** -0.26**<br />
(0.127) (0.127)<br />
Firm size -0.12 -0.12<br />
(0.293) (0.293)<br />
Firm age 0.005 0.005<br />
(0.010) (0.010)<br />
Organizationally Organizationally<br />
Innovation dependent vs. -0.15 dependent 0.23<br />
behavior socially embedded3 (0.246) vs. lame4 (0.234)<br />
Lame vs. socially -0.37** Socially 0.37**<br />
embedded3 (0.170) embedded vs. lame4 (0.170)<br />
Overall effect5 —* —*<br />
Prob > chi2 0.0006 0.0006<br />
Pseudo R square 0.047 0.047<br />
Number of observations 233 233<br />
1 Product innovation outcome refers to improvement in product quality, product function and product categorical<br />
upgrading<br />
2 Initial product as low-tech as the default group, which means low-tech as 0, the other as 1<br />
3 Socially embedded innovator as the default group, which means socially embedded innovator as 0, the other as 1<br />
4 Lame innovator as the default group, which means lame innovator as 0, the other as 1<br />
5 T test of whether the overall effect of the categorical variable is statistically significant<br />
6 Standard errors in parentheses; *p
Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 93<br />
only as a ‘spying device’ to catch up with the<br />
latest technology and market preferences in order<br />
to trigger new product ideas. The more <strong>und</strong>erdeveloped<br />
firm capabilities of domestic<br />
firms compared to those of foreign firms, resulting<br />
in less gain from reciprocity than the<br />
cost of spillover, inhibit them from cooperating<br />
in the product innovation process to share each<br />
other’s codified and tacit knowledge.<br />
Impact of proximities on product innovation<br />
performance<br />
The results of the Tobit regression with innovation<br />
performance as the dependent variable and<br />
innovation behavior and other control variables<br />
as independent variables are shown in Tab. 5.<br />
The results of the cluster analysis are used to<br />
define the innovation behavior as: 1 - socially<br />
embedded innovators, 2 - organizationally dependent<br />
innovators and 3 - lame innovators.<br />
The chi-square likelihood ratio has a p-value of<br />
0.002, which tells us, that the model as a whole<br />
fits significantly better than an empty model.<br />
The main focus of the research question is the<br />
impact of the use of proximity on product innovation<br />
performance. Equation 1 and equation<br />
2 are quite similar, with the exception that<br />
the default group of each dummy variable in<br />
the innovation behavior category is adjusted to<br />
compare the impact of each type of innovation<br />
behavior on innovation performance. If control<br />
variables for firm characteristics and absorptive<br />
capacity are included in the model, socially<br />
embedded innovators possess a better product<br />
innovation outcome than lame innovators<br />
on a significant level of 0.02, while organizationally<br />
dependent innovators do not outperform<br />
the lame innovator in a significant way.<br />
This verifies the second hypothesis that social<br />
proximity is an asset that firms are able to capitalize<br />
on in complex innovation processes.<br />
With the development of local capabilities in<br />
the Pearl River Delta after thirty years of industrialization,<br />
firms are gradually accumulating<br />
the capacity to capitalize on social proximity<br />
to foster product innovation and upgrading.<br />
Nevertheless, it also suggests that firms that<br />
apply the strategies of capitalizing on organizational<br />
proximity to foster innovation encounter<br />
the difficulty of achieving satisfied innovation<br />
outcomes. The limited potential for upgrading<br />
the position in the value chain is revealed for<br />
organizationally dependent innovators, supporting<br />
the first hypothesis.<br />
Nevertheless, it is necessary to examine cautiously<br />
the magnitude of improvement by applying<br />
social proximity in interactive learning.<br />
The coefficients in model 1 and model 2 all<br />
point to a 0.37 degree of improvement on the<br />
average score of evaluation on production<br />
function expansion and category upgrading. To<br />
place it in a practical context, this means that<br />
applying social proximity in interactive learning<br />
promotes the innovation outcome either in<br />
function expansion or category upgrading by<br />
nearly one degree (e.g. from not significant to<br />
slightly significant or from significant to very<br />
significant). In short, the improvement made<br />
by applying social proximity compared to applying<br />
nothing is rather small. Moreover, socially<br />
embedded innovators, which interact<br />
with domestic customers and other knowledge<br />
institutions in the process of product innovation,<br />
do not differ significantly from organizationally<br />
dependent innovators in terms of product<br />
innovation performance.<br />
The results reveal an intriguing feature of the<br />
recent development stage of the regional innovation<br />
system in the Pearl River Delta. Although<br />
socially embedded firms are emerging<br />
in this region, which altogether increases dynamic<br />
innovative synergies on the local scale,<br />
their capacity to transform this social asset fully<br />
into a high innovation performance is not yet<br />
sufficient. Recalling the results in the previous<br />
section which revealed that domestic firms are<br />
reluctant to share codified and tacit knowledge<br />
in the innovation process, this all <strong>und</strong>erpins the<br />
instability of innovative synergies in emerging<br />
regions where small achievements are not sufficient<br />
to compensate for the risk and cost related<br />
to innovation activities. It might be due to<br />
the fact that trust building requires time, especially<br />
in innovation activities that are highly<br />
complex and risky and involve a high level of<br />
spillover effects. All in all, a regional innovation<br />
system is only just burgeoning in the Pearl<br />
River Delta, and calls for a stable and efficient<br />
governance infrastructure to be put in place to<br />
strengthen and stabilize interactive learning in<br />
the business sector.<br />
Discussion and conclusion<br />
The fact that the local firms are interested and<br />
able to capitalize on social proximity to foster<br />
innovation signifies the maturing of a regional<br />
innovation system (COOKE et al. 1997; REVIL-<br />
LA DIEZ 2000). Moreover, the use of organiza-
94 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
tional proximity feeds dynamism into the local<br />
production system as a way of avoiding negative<br />
lock-in effects (ASHEIM/ISAKSEN 2002;<br />
BATHELT et al. 2004). In the context of China,<br />
where low-cost is the common strategy and innovation<br />
capability is doubted, this paper provides<br />
the theoretical implications of the role of<br />
proximity in fostering innovation activities<br />
when sufficient absorptive capacity is gradually<br />
enhanced. The line of thinking that social<br />
capital is an important asset for organizing interactive<br />
learning and markets is well covered<br />
by the institutional and cultural turn in many<br />
disciplines. In new growth theory, productive<br />
new ideas are endogenously shaped by institutional<br />
contexts (ROMER 1986). The approach of<br />
innovation systems proposes that social capital<br />
induces widely spread interactive learning in<br />
the whole economy, hence creating more net<br />
wealth (LUNDVALL 2005). Likewise, the new<br />
institutionalism in economic geography also<br />
embraces the context-dependent epistemology,<br />
considering the possibility that various social<br />
institutions in places determine the evolution<br />
of the economic landscape (CLARK et al. 2003).<br />
As demonstrated by the empirical investigation<br />
in this paper, the informal guanxi networks in<br />
the Chinese context are important social assets<br />
that firms can take advantage of in ensuring effective<br />
interactive learning.<br />
By examining the questionnaire data collected<br />
for the electronics industry in the Pearl River<br />
Delta, the following trends are captured in this<br />
electronics cluster. Firstly, as organizational<br />
proximity plays a limited role in promoting innovation,<br />
the electronics firms have extended<br />
the use of social proximity from low-cost production<br />
activities to <strong>und</strong>ertake interactive<br />
learning in the product innovation process. Despite<br />
the formation of a group of socially embedded<br />
firms, the effect of social proximity in<br />
fostering fruitful interactive learning is still<br />
marginal. Secondly, social proximity is applied<br />
more by domestic firms than by foreign firms,<br />
especially in terms of triggering new product<br />
ideas. However, it is applied less by the domestic<br />
firms to gain support in the innovation<br />
process, such as necessary machinery and technical<br />
know-how. Altogether, social proximity<br />
not only produces marginal effects, but also<br />
has limited scope in strengthening the interactive<br />
learning in innovation, which all points to<br />
the instability of innovation synergies that is<br />
stressed in the regional competitiveness literature.<br />
Even before the financial crisis in 2008, governments<br />
at different levels (province, city, district)<br />
in the Pearl River Delta felt that the strategy<br />
of low-cost production was losing its competitive<br />
edge and had been eagerly promoting<br />
industrial upgrading and innovation. As interactive<br />
learning processes based on social relations<br />
need stabilizing regional orders from the<br />
supporting governance infrastructure (HEIDEN-<br />
REICH 2004), policy focus may be devoted to<br />
widening the scope of social proximity in interactive<br />
learning and improving the effect of<br />
social proximity in fostering innovation, which<br />
has been pointed out from the empirical results<br />
as a weakness of the regional innovation system<br />
in the Pearl River Delta. Actions can be<br />
taken by means of supporting agents or organizations<br />
to foster cooperation among local players<br />
as well as with external players, institutionalizing<br />
the exchange and learning between industry<br />
and academia, regulating the domestic<br />
market which stabilizes the reciprocal learning<br />
among the firms, and providing innovation<br />
f<strong>und</strong>s to resource-limited small and medium<br />
enterprises.<br />
The theoretical literature has extensively discussed<br />
the issue of proximity and its relationship<br />
with learning and behavior, but the empirical<br />
evidence is not yet sufficient to support its<br />
role in innovation in different contexts, especially<br />
that of developing countries. This paper<br />
takes the step of measuring the use of the two<br />
most relevant proximities – organizational<br />
proximity and social proximity – in the context<br />
of China. By responding to the call of researching<br />
the knowledge transfer and learning<br />
process at global and local scales (BUN-<br />
NELL/COE 2001; ASHEIM/ISAKSEN 2002; FREE-<br />
MAN 2002; FROMHOLD-EISEBITH 2007) light<br />
was thrown on the role of proximity on both<br />
scales in attaining trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding in<br />
the process of product innovation. However,<br />
the complementary role of organizational proximity<br />
with global partners and social proximity<br />
with local partners is not simple. As demonstrated<br />
by HUMPHREY/SCHMITZ (2002), different<br />
degrees of organizational proximity, i.e.<br />
different methods of integration into the global<br />
production system, actually influence the local<br />
upgrading strategies. Therefore, qualitative<br />
studies such as company interviews should be<br />
conducted to provide further insight into the<br />
strategic combination of different proximities<br />
to achieve the optimal innovation outcome.
Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 95<br />
Acknowledgement<br />
The research <strong>und</strong>erlying the results presented<br />
in this paper received f<strong>und</strong>ing from the German<br />
Research Fo<strong>und</strong>ation (DFG) <strong>und</strong>er grant<br />
RE 1720/11-1 within the priority programme<br />
SPP 1233 “Megacities – Megachallenge: Informal<br />
Dynamics of Global Change”. The authors<br />
would like to thank two anonymous referees<br />
for their comments on the paper.<br />
References<br />
ASHEIM, B. T./ISAKSEN, A. (2002): Regional innovation<br />
systems: the integration of local ‘sticky’ and global<br />
‘ubiquitous’ knowledge. In: The Journal of Technology<br />
Transfer, (27)1, 77-86.<br />
ASHEIM, B. T./COENEN, L. (2005): Knowledge bases and<br />
regional innovation systems: Comparing Nordic clusters.<br />
In: Research policy, (34)8, 1173-1190.<br />
BATHELT, H./MALMBERG, A./MASKELL, P. (2004): Clusters<br />
and knowledge: local buzz, global pipelines and the<br />
process of knowledge creation. In: Progress in Human<br />
Geography, (28)1, 31-56.<br />
BELLANDI, M./TOMMASO, M. R. (2005): The case of specialized<br />
towns in Guangdong, China. In: European<br />
Planning Studies, (13)5, 707-729.<br />
BOSCHMA, R. (2005): Proximity and innovation. A critical<br />
assessment. In: Regional Studies, (39)1, 61-74.<br />
BUNNELL, T. G./COE, N. M. (2001): Spaces and scales of<br />
innovation. In: Progress in Human geography, (25)4,<br />
569-589.<br />
CAPELLO, R. (1999): Spatial transfer of knowledge in<br />
high technology milieu. Learning versus collective<br />
learning processes. In: Regional Studies, (33)4, 353-<br />
365.<br />
CHESBROUGH, H. W./TEECE, D. J. (1996): When is virtual<br />
virtuous. In: Harvard Business Review, (74)1, 65-73.<br />
CLARK, G. L./FELDMAN, M. P./GERTLER, M. S. (2003):<br />
The Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford,<br />
USA.<br />
COOKE, P./URANDA, M. G./ETXEBARRIA, G. (1997): Regional<br />
innovation systems: <strong>Institut</strong>ional and organizational<br />
dimensions. In: Research Policy, (26), 475-491.<br />
DELMAR, F./DAVIDSSON, P./GARTNER, W. (2003): Arriving<br />
at the high growth firm. In: Journal of Business Venturing,<br />
(18)2, 189-216.<br />
DICKEN, P. (1976): Multiplant business, enterprise and<br />
geographical space. Some issues in the study of external<br />
control and regional development. In: Regional Studies,<br />
(10)4, 401-412.<br />
DOLLAR, D. (2005): Globalization, inequality, and<br />
poverty since 1980. In: World Bank Research Observer,<br />
(20)2: 145-175.<br />
DOLOREUX, D./PARTO, S. (2005): Regional innovation<br />
systems. Current discourse and challenges for future research.<br />
In: Technology in Society, (27)2, 133-153.<br />
ERNST, D. (2005): The new mobility of knowledge: digital<br />
information systems and global flagship networks.<br />
In: Latham,R./Sassen, S. (Eds.): Digital formations. IT<br />
and new architectures in the global realm. Princeton,<br />
S. 89-114.<br />
ERNST, D./KIM, L. (2002): Global production networks,<br />
knowledge diffusion, and local capability formation. In:<br />
Research Policy, (31), 1417-1429.<br />
FREEMAN, C. (2002): Continental, national and sub-national<br />
innovation systems. Complementarity and economic<br />
growth. In: Research Policy, (31)2, 191-211.<br />
FEINBERG, S. E./GUPTA, A. K. (2004): Knowledge<br />
spillovers and the assignment of R&D responsibilities<br />
to foreign subsidiaries. In: Strategic Management Journal,<br />
(25)8-9, 823-845.<br />
FROMHOLD-EISEBITH, M. (2007): Bridging scales in innovation<br />
policies. How to link regional, national and international<br />
innovation systems. In: European Planning<br />
Studies, (15)2, 217-233.<br />
GEREFFI, G./HUMPHREY, J./STURGEON, T. (2005): The<br />
governance of global value chains. In: Review of International<br />
Political Economy, (12)1, 78-104.<br />
GRANOVETTER, M. (1985): Economic action and social<br />
structure. The problem of embeddedness. In: American<br />
Journal of Sociology, (91)3, 481-510.<br />
HEIDENREICH, M. (2004): The dilemmas of regional<br />
innnovation systems. In Cooke, P./Heidenreich,<br />
M./Braczyk, H. J. (Eds.): Regional innovation systems.<br />
The role of governance in a globalized world. London,<br />
363-394. (2nd ed.).<br />
HENNART, J. F. (1993): Explaining the swollen middle.<br />
Why most transactions are a mix of market and hierarchy.<br />
In: Organization Science, (4)4, 529-547.<br />
HSU, J. Y./SAXENIAN, A. (2000): The limits of guanxi<br />
capitalism. Transnational collaboration between Taiwan<br />
and the USA. In: Environment and Planning A, (32)11,<br />
1991-2005.<br />
HUMPHREY, J./SCHMITZ, H. (2002): How does insertion<br />
in global value chains affect upgrading in industrial<br />
clusters? In: Regional studies, (36)9, 1017-1027.<br />
HUMPHREY, J. (2004): Upgrading in global value chains.<br />
Geneva. (ILO).<br />
HOWELLS, J. R. L. (1999): Regional systems of innovation?<br />
Cambridge.<br />
IVARSSON, I./ALVSTAM, C. G. (2005): The effect of spatial<br />
proximity on technology transfer from TNCs to local<br />
suppliers in developing countries. The case of AB<br />
Volvo in Asia and Latin America. In: Economic Geography,<br />
(81)1, 83-111.<br />
KIRAT, T./LUNG, Y. (1999): Innovation and proximity.<br />
Territories as loci of collective learning processes. In:<br />
European Urban and Regional Studies, (6)1, 27-38.<br />
LONG, J. S. (1997): Regression models for categorical<br />
and limited dependent variables. Chapter 7. Thousand<br />
Oaks.<br />
LOVETT, S./SIMMONS, L. C./KALI, R. (1999): Guanxi<br />
versus the market. Ethics and efficiency. In: Journal of<br />
International Business Studies, (30)2, 231-247.
96 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
LUNDVALL, B. A. (1992): National innovation systems.<br />
Towards a theory of innovation and interactive learning.<br />
London.<br />
LUNDVALL, B. A. (2005): Interactive learning, social capital<br />
and economic performance. Paper presented at the<br />
“Advancing Knowledge and the Knowledge Economy”,<br />
Washington, D.C., 10-11 Jan. 2005. Washington, D.C.<br />
MASKELL, P. (1998): Low-tech competitive advantages<br />
and the role of proximity. In: European Urban and Regional<br />
Studies, (5)2, 99-118.<br />
MASSARD, N./MEHIER, C. (2009): Proximity and Innovation<br />
through an “Accessibility to Knowledge” Lens.<br />
In: Regional Studies, (43)1, 77-88.<br />
MENZEL, M. P. (2008): Dynamic proximities. Changing<br />
relations by creating and bridging distances. Utrecht.<br />
(Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography, Urban<br />
and Regional Research Centre, Universiteit Utrecht,<br />
working papers).<br />
MEYER, S./SCHILLER, D./REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2009): The<br />
Janus-faced economy. Hong Kong firms as intermediaries<br />
between global customers and local producers in<br />
the electronics industry. In: Tijdschrift Voor Economische<br />
En Sociale Geografie, (100)2, 224-235.<br />
MORRISON, A./PIETROBELLI, C./RABELLOTT, R. (2008):<br />
Global value chains and technological capabilities. A<br />
framework to study learning and innovation in developing<br />
countries. In: Oxford Development Studies, (36)1,<br />
39-58.<br />
NELSON, R. R./WINTER, S. G. (1982): An evolutionary<br />
theory of economic change. Bonston.<br />
NORTH, D. C. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change,<br />
and economic performance. Cambridge.<br />
OECD (1998): Main science and technology indicators.<br />
Paris.<br />
PAN, Y. G./CHI, P. S. K. (1999): Financial performance<br />
and survival of multinational corporations in China. In:<br />
Strategic Management Journal, (20)4, 359-374.<br />
PARK, S. H./LUO, Y. D. (2001): Guanxi and organizational<br />
dynamics. Organizational networking in Chinese<br />
firms. In: Strategic Management Journal, (22)5, 455-477.<br />
PENG, M. W. (2003): Extending research on network<br />
strategy in emerging economics. Hong Kong. (The Chinese<br />
University of Hong Kong: Strategic Management<br />
Society Mini-Conference).<br />
PORTER, M. E. (1990): The competitive advantage of nations.<br />
New York.<br />
RAMASAMY, B./GOH, K. W./YEUNG, M. C. H. (2006): Is<br />
Guanxi (relationship) a bridge to knowledge transfer?<br />
In: Journal of Business Research, (59)1, 130-139.<br />
REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2000): The importance of public research<br />
institutes in innovative networks. Empirical results<br />
from the Metropolitan innovation systems<br />
Barcelona, Stockholm and Vienna. In: European Planning<br />
Studies, (8)4, 451-463.<br />
ROMER, P. M. (1986): Increasing returns and long-run<br />
growth. In: Journal of Political Economy, (94)5, 1002-<br />
1037.<br />
SCHMITZ, H. (1995): Small shoemakers and Fordist giants.<br />
Tale of a supercluster. In: World Development,<br />
(23)1, 9-28.<br />
SCHMITZ, H./NADVI, K. (1999): Clustering and industrialization.<br />
Introduction. In: World Development, (27)9,<br />
1503-1514.<br />
SMITH, K. (2000): Innovation as a systemic phenomenon:<br />
rethinking the role of policy. In: Enterprise and innovation<br />
management studies, (1)1, 73-102.<br />
STANDIFIRD, S. S./ MARSHALL, R. S. (2000): The transaction<br />
cost advantage of guanxi-based business practices.<br />
In: Journal of World Business, (35)1, 21-42.<br />
TORRE, A./GILLY, J. P. (2000): On the analytical dimension<br />
of proximity dynamics. In: Regional Studies,<br />
(34)2, 169-180.<br />
TORRE, A./RALLETT, A. (2005): Proximity and localization.<br />
In: Regional Studies, (39)1, 47-59.<br />
YANG, C. (2009): Strategic coupling of regional development<br />
in global production networks. Redistribution<br />
of Taiwanese personal computer investment from the<br />
Pearl River Delta to the Yangtze River Delta, China. In:<br />
Regional Studies, (43)3, 385-407.<br />
YEUNG, H. W. (2006): Regional development and the<br />
competitive dynamics of global production networks.<br />
An East Asian perspective. In: Regional Studies, (43)3,<br />
325-351.<br />
ZHANG, Y./ZHANG, Z. G. (2006): Guanxi and organizational<br />
dynamics in China. A link between individual and<br />
organizational levels. In: Journal of Business Ethics,<br />
(67)4, 375-392.<br />
ZHOU, X./LI, Q./ZHAO, W./CAI, H. (2003): Embeddedness<br />
and contractual relationships in China’s transition<br />
economy. In: American Sociological Review, (68)1, 75-<br />
102.
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 97-112<br />
Friederike Schröder / Michael Waibel, Hamburg<br />
Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta<br />
Investigating economic restructuring in Guangzhou<br />
Abstract: Against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of current economic upgrading trends in China’s so called “factory<br />
of the world“, the Pearl River Delta, this paper adopts an analytical urban governance perspective<br />
to investigate the role of informality in urban affairs. In the wake of dynamic economic<br />
and urban growth coinciding with rising environmental and social issues, local governments increasingly<br />
re-orientate their urban development strategies and apply flexible modes in responding<br />
to these challenges. The main hypothesis of this paper is that informality in particular is used as a<br />
tool of flexibility and that experimental policies as typical characteristics of the transitional<br />
process in China are widely applied nowadays to attract knowledge-intensive and service-oriented<br />
industries as well as a highly educated, and presumably creative, workforce. The hypothesis is<br />
validated by empirical research analyzing governance processes in development and locational<br />
policies of Guangzhou Science City.<br />
Keywords: urban governance, informality, economic restructuring, Guangzhou. Pearl River Delta<br />
Introduction<br />
The Pearl River Delta (PRD) as the “factory of<br />
the world” and frontrunner of China’s reform<br />
and opening process witnesses a new phase in<br />
the gradual transition process. Immense efforts<br />
have been done to move from a mere focus on<br />
growth and spatial expansion towards restructuring<br />
of the existing urban fabric and the cities’<br />
economic base. There is a policy shift away<br />
from labor-intensive production towards higher<br />
value-added manufacturing and service industries<br />
and to a more knowledge-based economy<br />
in general. This has been going on for some<br />
years already, but gained substantial impetus<br />
due to the global financial crisis, which can be<br />
seen as an important catalyst for economic restructuring<br />
and upgrading in the PRD region.<br />
The growth of the tertiary and quarternary sectors<br />
calls for constant economic and urban redevelopment<br />
processes and adaptation strategies<br />
that allow for different spatial economic<br />
entities to be attractive for companies and the<br />
global as well as the domestic workforce.<br />
Economic restructuring and changing urban development<br />
strategies entail the thesis that these<br />
transformations also bring about a change in ur-<br />
ban governance modes or the way a city or urban<br />
area is governed. Therefore, the <strong>und</strong>erlying<br />
assumption is that a diversifying society, and<br />
particularly the ongoing economic restructuring<br />
process in the PRD, require new formal and informal<br />
institutional arrangements, i.e. changing<br />
modes of urban governance and specific sets of<br />
stakeholder coalitions. We presume that in this<br />
process informality, <strong>und</strong>erstood here as a mode<br />
rather than a sector (ROY/ALSAYAD 2004), is increasingly<br />
used as a tool of flexibility, testing,<br />
and learning, whereas informality – used as a<br />
substitute to fill institutional gaps in the early<br />
phase of transition – has diminished over time<br />
in the course of the reform process.<br />
Economic restructuring implies a re-production<br />
of space. In the PRD, it takes place by comprehensive<br />
planning approaches loosening the<br />
strict division between industrial and urban<br />
space, integrating various urban functions and<br />
by upgrading the urban fabric intended to raise<br />
urban liveability. How is urban space developed<br />
and reproduced? And how are locational policies<br />
implemented against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of a<br />
changing economic base? These are the main<br />
questions to be answered in this paper. They include<br />
questions of who is involved in planning
98 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
and implementation and what are the objectives.<br />
Following these questions, our overall<br />
aim is to analyze urban governance processes<br />
in Guangzhou, China. As an analytical tool, the<br />
integrated framework of urban governance developed<br />
by DIGAETANO/STROM (2003) will be<br />
applied and consequently adapted to the Chinese<br />
context.<br />
For the case study, Guangzhou Science City<br />
(GSC), particularly its physical development<br />
and locational policies as a high-tech park and<br />
urban environment, have been chosen. The role<br />
of informality as potentially flexible device in<br />
these processes will be of special interest. As<br />
priority project of Guangzhou’s municipal<br />
government, designed to upgrade the economic<br />
structure along the value chain, GSC is an extraordinary<br />
example for the interplay of economic<br />
upgrading and comprehensive urban development<br />
strategies. It is currently one of the<br />
most ambitious and prominent urban development<br />
projects in the PRD since the construction<br />
of flagship high-tech industrial parks has been<br />
promoted by the National Development and<br />
Reform Commission in 2008 as a key strategy<br />
of the regional upgrading of Guangdong<br />
province.<br />
The questions and arguments are analyzed and<br />
presented in three main parts. The first analyzes<br />
economic restructuring in the PRD. The second<br />
discusses the concepts of governance and informality<br />
and relates both to the context of China.<br />
The third section applies our research approach<br />
to the case study of Guangzhou Science City<br />
and discusses the role of informality in urban<br />
governance processes in the field of urban economic<br />
restructuring.<br />
Economic restructuring in the<br />
Pearl River Delta<br />
In Europe and North America economic restructuring<br />
has mostly been a necessity of the<br />
fall of regional economies or declining of industrial<br />
centers (HASSINK 2005, 571, FAINSTEIN/<br />
CAMPBELL 2002, 6). In China, and particularly<br />
in the Pearl River Delta with average yearly<br />
GDP growth rates of 14 % between 2000 and<br />
2009 (Tab. 1), rising salaries and living standards,<br />
and a fast growth in urban population<br />
one can barely speak of a declining region.<br />
However, high speed economic and urban development,<br />
hastily built-up infrastructure, the<br />
superimposition of new and old physical structures,<br />
traffic congestion, environmental degradation,<br />
spatial fragmentation and social segregation<br />
take their toll. These processes call the<br />
need for restructuring of the existing urban fabric<br />
and economic base.<br />
The PRD has experienced tremendous economic<br />
growth and spatial transformation since the<br />
late 1970s. It differs from the Yangtze Delta<br />
River (YDR) in the way that its economic development<br />
and urbanization process is mainly<br />
the result of exogenous forces, such as foreign<br />
direct investments (FDI), influences from the<br />
Chinese diaspora of Hong Kong, Singapore,<br />
and other parts of the world, and small to medium-sized<br />
labor-intensive processing manufacturing.<br />
In contrast, the development pace of the<br />
YDR rather results from endogenous dynamisms<br />
and agglomeration advantages from<br />
the major city of Shanghai (HE et al. 2006,<br />
431). Though dominated by external forces, internal<br />
factors – apparently affecting all regions<br />
of China – also play a role in the PRD’s development,<br />
i.e. institutional changes and innovations,<br />
fiscal decentralization and fierce inter-urban<br />
competition. It is the interdependency of<br />
different structural, cultural, and political forces<br />
that have unevenly transformed the economic,<br />
social, physical and spatial landscapes in the<br />
PRD (HE et al. 2006, 436; SHEN 2002, 92) – and<br />
transformation is still going on.<br />
Agricultural diversification and industrialization<br />
of the 1980s and 1990s gives way to a new<br />
phase of economic restructuring with a deliberately<br />
induced shift away from labor-intensive<br />
manufacturing towards knowledge-intensive<br />
industries and a growth of the tertiary sector.<br />
“Building a modern industrial system” (NDRC<br />
2008, 15) is the programmatic device to prioritize<br />
the PRD’s development of modern service<br />
industries (e.g. finance, convention and exhibition<br />
services, scientific research and development),<br />
modernizing and advancing capital- and<br />
technology-intensive manufacturing industries<br />
(e.g. automotive, nuclear and wind power<br />
equipment), and vigorously develop high-tech<br />
industries (biotechnology, pharmaceutical<br />
products, new materials, computer, electronic<br />
and optical products) (loc. cit.). This new phase<br />
of economic restructuring can be dated back to<br />
China’s accession to the World Trade Organization<br />
(WTO) in 2001. The implementation of<br />
economic restructuring policies has gained substantial<br />
impetus in the wake of the “financial
F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 99<br />
tsunami”, as the global financial crisis was labeled<br />
in the PRD, that has laid off thousands of<br />
mostly migrant workers in the labor-intensive<br />
industries of textile, toys, and electronic production.<br />
Chinese governments at the national, provincial,<br />
and local levels (i.e. municipal and district-level<br />
governments) have recognized in recent<br />
years that the economic boom of the last<br />
three decades caused environmental costs and<br />
has raised social exclusion. Thus, there is a tendency<br />
away from a mere focus on economic<br />
growth towards policies promoting an improved<br />
quality of the urban economic and living<br />
environment and of social, health, and educational<br />
infrastructure.<br />
Recent statements made by party leaders illustrate<br />
the political momentum for economic upgrading.<br />
For example, Guangdong Communist<br />
Party Secretary Wang Yang maintained: “Our<br />
growth model of 30 years, which enriched us<br />
rapidly, has come to the end of its cycle. … Our<br />
mission is a tough one. We must convince them<br />
that we must change. The old ways of consuming<br />
resources and importing labor will not<br />
work. Even if we wanted to continue with it,<br />
we would be unable to do so – we are running<br />
out of resources and environmental capital.”<br />
And the Guangzhou Party Secretary Zhu Xiao-<br />
dan argued in a similar way: “We’ve paid a<br />
heavy price for rapid growth. (…) We will support<br />
companies at the high end of the value<br />
chain and use industrial parks as a driving<br />
force.” (KUHN 2009a-e) The deeper meaning of<br />
these quotations becomes clear when one considers<br />
the latest ideological framework formulated<br />
by the Communist Party of China (CPC)<br />
in 2003. In order to adapt and adequately cope<br />
with economic and socio-political challenges<br />
on the one hand as well as to maintain supreme<br />
authority and political legitimacy on the other,<br />
the CPCoffers rathervague, but formative ideological<br />
guidelines phrased <strong>und</strong>er the concept of<br />
“Socialism with Chinese characteristics”. Under<br />
this framework, Hu Jintao, General Secretary<br />
of the CPC and President of the PRC, has<br />
been promoting a new approach to developement,<br />
i.e. the “scientific development concept”.<br />
The stated idea behind this concept and behind<br />
scientific development is to “take people as the<br />
main thing, establish a concept of comprehensive,<br />
coordinated, sustainable development, and<br />
promote comprehensive economic, social, and<br />
human development” (FEWSMITH 2004, 3).<br />
Hence, “scientific development” is ultimately<br />
to lead to the construction of a “harmonious society”<br />
and will thus officially change China’s<br />
focus from mere economic growth to promoting<br />
economic, social, and environmental development<br />
(HEBERER/SCHUBERT 2008, 203;<br />
Tab. 1: GDP growth and per capita GDP in the Pearl River Delta and its two major cities<br />
Guangzhou and Shenzhen<br />
2000 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009<br />
Pearl River Delta (total)<br />
GDP growth (compared<br />
to previous year, %)<br />
Per capita GDP<br />
13.7 15.7 16.8 16.3 12.8 9.4<br />
(in Chinese Yuan)<br />
Guangzhou<br />
GDP growth (compared<br />
20,280 40,336 47,241 55,048 63,065 67,407<br />
to previous year, %)<br />
Per capita GDP<br />
13.3 12.9 14.9 15.3 12.5 11.7<br />
(in Chinese Yuan)<br />
Shenzhen<br />
GDP growth (compared<br />
25,626 53,809 63,184 72,123 81,941 89,082<br />
to previous year, %) 15.7 15.1 16.6 14.8 12.1 10.7<br />
Per capita GDP<br />
(in Chinese Yuan)<br />
32,800 60,801 69,450 79,645 89,587 92,772<br />
Source: Guangdong Statistical Yearbook 2010
100 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
SCHOON 2011). Evidently, those slogans are still<br />
<strong>und</strong>erfed with a great deal of propaganda, but<br />
the implementation of economic restructuring<br />
policies can be certainly regarded as an essential<br />
step towards an economy that is less polluting<br />
and offers a higher quality of life.<br />
Trickled down to the provincial level, the new<br />
guiding principle has led to the most important<br />
cornerstone of economic upgrading and restructuring<br />
in the PRD, the “Plan for the reform and<br />
development of the Pearl River Delta (2008-<br />
2020)” issued by the National Development<br />
and Reform Commission in December 2008<br />
(SCHRÖDER/WAIBEL 2010, 2). Its main aim is to<br />
build up a maturing industrial system by prioritizing<br />
the development of modern service industries,<br />
as well as vigorously speeding up the<br />
development of advanced manufacturing with a<br />
focus on high-tech development. The plan promotes<br />
to substantially increase “gross domestic<br />
expenditure on research and development”<br />
(GERD) investments. Embedded into the central<br />
government’s initiatives such as the<br />
Eleventh Five Year Plan for National Economic<br />
and Social Development of PR China or the<br />
Program for Mid- and Long-term Development<br />
of Science & Technology (2006 to 2020) this<br />
means an envisaged increase of research and<br />
development (R&D) intensity to 2.5 % of GDP<br />
until 2020 1 (loc.cit.).<br />
With regard to this paper’s question of how urban<br />
spaces are developed and locational policies<br />
are implemented against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of<br />
economic restructuring, a very important and<br />
often <strong>und</strong>erestimated factor of relevance for<br />
China’s rapid and constantly high economic<br />
growth over the last 30 years is the pragmatic<br />
and flexible experimental approach. It has been<br />
introduced by the post-Mao regime to test economic<br />
reforms in distinct spatial entities first<br />
and, in the case of success, extend them to other<br />
regions in the country. In the Western conventional<br />
<strong>und</strong>erstanding, legislation takes place<br />
in advance of implementation. In China (and in<br />
other transitional countries such as Vietnam),<br />
the mode of testing or experimenting and therefore<br />
implementation before formal legislation<br />
has proved a pragmatic tool in this rapidly<br />
changing and highly heterogeneous spatial,<br />
structural, and socio-economic environment (LIN<br />
2001, 387; NG/TANG 2004, 181). Reformer Deng<br />
Xiaoping famously characterized this experimental<br />
approach as “groping the stones while<br />
crossing the river”. Experimental forms of gov-<br />
ernance mostly include the informal testing of<br />
strategies or tools before formalizing them. The<br />
Pearl River Delta region is a perfect showcase<br />
for this experimental strategy.<br />
This has also wider implications in terms of urban<br />
governance. As our research shows, the development<br />
of Guangzhou Science City (GSC) is<br />
accompanied by a high flexibility and experimental<br />
character that involves a change in the relationship<br />
between private companies and the local<br />
state. This change became necessary because<br />
state officials needed to cooperate with private<br />
companies to achieve their predetermined development<br />
goals. Before going into the case study,<br />
we will have a closer look at the concepts of urban<br />
governance and informality illustrating their<br />
value for analyzing economic restructuring and<br />
the reproduction of space in Guangzhou.<br />
Narrowing the <strong>und</strong>erstanding of urban<br />
governance and informality<br />
Governance is an ambiguous concept developed<br />
from a discourse mainly in North America and<br />
Western Europe. It deals with socio-economic<br />
interdependencies that have been changing<br />
since the late 1970s (JESSOP 1995, 309; KOOI-<br />
MAN 2005, 150; MAYNTZ 2005, 13). It emphasizes<br />
that the idea of the state as key actor in political<br />
decision-making, its exclusive responsibility<br />
for fulfilling state functions and duties, as<br />
well as its influence on the economy and society<br />
is increasingly changing. This often implies a<br />
shift in <strong>und</strong>erstanding of political processes<br />
away from government towards governance.<br />
Whereas government denotes decision-making<br />
that lies solely within the state and its institutions,<br />
governance refers to altered interrelations<br />
between state, society, and the economy and the<br />
increasing importance of less directive forms of<br />
political regulation (cooperative and non-hierarchical),<br />
e.g., political coordination or negotiation<br />
in networks (PIERRE/PETERS 2000, 12).<br />
Can such an admittedly fuzzy concept, stressing<br />
the increasing role of non-hierarchical forms of<br />
regulation, help to <strong>und</strong>erstand highly state-controlled<br />
processes in urban China? The authors<br />
believe that this question must be answered in<br />
the affirmative. First of all, the emergence of the<br />
governance paradigm stands for the adoption of<br />
a wider analytical perspective in political science.<br />
Secondly, it is maintained that <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
it as an analytical concept (rather than as
F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 101<br />
manifestation of a postulated changed global reality)<br />
(PIERRE 2005, 451ff.) can create an awareness<br />
of structures and processes influencing policymaking<br />
that would otherwise be overlooked.<br />
Processes describe what actors can do, i.e., regulation<br />
(via incentives or hierarchical command)<br />
or coordination (BENZ et al. 2007, 16; PIERRE/<br />
PETERS 2000, 22). Structures are <strong>und</strong>erstood here<br />
as institutional contexts in which actors are able<br />
to operate (hierarchies, markets, networks, communities,<br />
associations). This allows analyzing<br />
how regulation and coordination occur within a<br />
defined policy field, such as economic restructuring,<br />
or in a spatially distinguished area. With<br />
regard to China’s gradual transition process and<br />
its highly dynamic urban development processes<br />
serving as arena for current economic upgrading<br />
processes, this analytical governance approach<br />
helps to entangle the complex forces <strong>und</strong>erlying<br />
urban affairs in China.<br />
Urban governance<br />
In comparative urban politics, governance is<br />
conceived as a coordination process of political<br />
Fig. 1: Integrative model of urban governance<br />
Source: DIGAETANTO/STROM 2003, 372; modified<br />
decisions in the urban and economic spheres.<br />
Derived from the structural perspective of political<br />
economy, it is based on the notion that governing<br />
procedures at the national, regional, and<br />
local levels; market forces; and economic as<br />
well as social structures set the context of urban<br />
governance (DIGAETANO/STROM 2003, 362).<br />
However, an exclusively structural approach often<br />
lacks an encompassing consideration of the<br />
complex set of influences and processes in urban<br />
affairs, such as cultural impacts as well as<br />
the different actors and stakeholders involved.<br />
This is particularly problematic in China, which<br />
is influenced, among other aspects, by a long<br />
tradition of cultural factors and the influential<br />
role of powerful leaders (such as Mao Zedong or<br />
Deng Xiaoping). The significant deficiency of<br />
single-level explanation is surmounted by the<br />
comprehensive approach of DIGAETANO/STROM<br />
(2003), the biggest advantage of which is the integration<br />
of three middle-range theories, i.e.,<br />
structuralism, culturalism, and rational choice.<br />
With its merit as integrative analytical tool, this<br />
approach will be subject to our analysis of go-
102 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
verning structures in terms of economic restructuring<br />
in Guangzhou.<br />
DIGAETANO/STROM (2003) have highlighted the<br />
importance of each approach, structural, cultural,<br />
and rational-choice, as well as their dynamic<br />
interdependencies. Therefore, they have endeavored<br />
to integrate all three into a single<br />
framework. As an outcome, three interrelated<br />
levels of analysis are identified: (1) The structural<br />
context (e.g. political decentralization,<br />
transition, economic globalization) frames political<br />
decision-making, including over time; (2)<br />
political culture (beliefs, values, symbols) gives<br />
meaning to political organization and decisionmaking<br />
2; and (3) political actors who attempt to<br />
influence governmental decision-making in<br />
ways that benefit themselves and the interests<br />
they represent. In this context, political actors<br />
include all actors participating in urban governance<br />
processes, i.e., public as well as private<br />
and social actors or stakeholders. The three<br />
spheres of analysis trickle down to influence the<br />
institutional milieu, <strong>und</strong>erstood as the set of all<br />
formal and informal institutions that moderate<br />
the different analytical spheres and are crucial<br />
for their integration (Fig. 1).<br />
The role of informality<br />
Informality plays a crucial role when looking at<br />
governance processes, since it is evident that no<br />
political system, not even in the liberal democracies<br />
of Western Europe, functions solely on<br />
the basis of formal structures and processes<br />
(DANIELS 2004). Decision-making or political<br />
systems are not only the sum of formal institutional<br />
structures, but a mixture of formal and informal<br />
institutions (DIGAETANO/STROM 2003,<br />
363). We <strong>und</strong>erstand institutions (both formal<br />
and informal) with regard to the work of NORTH<br />
(1990: 3) as “rules of the game in a society or<br />
[…] the humanly devised constraints that shape<br />
human interaction”.<br />
Informality in urban and economic development<br />
processes takes place within a complex set of relationships<br />
between different actors, regulations,<br />
and ways of decision-making. It is thus <strong>und</strong>erstood<br />
here as interaction-related institution<br />
defining informality according to social or economic<br />
interaction. This interaction-related informality<br />
is associated with “contractual relationships<br />
between different individuals or organizations<br />
(tiers of government may be among them,<br />
but do not embody the state as producer of legal<br />
norms)” (ALTROCK et al. 2008, 5). It describes<br />
all forms of political activities that are not traceable<br />
and laid down in written documents. These<br />
may be debates and discussions that find consideration<br />
in decision-making processes beyond<br />
a legal framework as well as all interaction between<br />
individuals and organizations, that accompany<br />
planning processes or contracts, but<br />
are not written down. Interaction-related informality<br />
can contribute to mutual <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
without explicit interaction and thus reduce<br />
complexity while enhancing flexibility (loc.<br />
cit.).<br />
Despite a seemingly clear distinction between<br />
formal and informal constraints, no single political<br />
procedure can be characterized as being of<br />
either formal or informal character altogether<br />
(KIRCHBERGER 2004, 10). Thus, informality is<br />
not necessarily contradictory to formal processes<br />
or official rules, neither should it be <strong>und</strong>erstood<br />
as a deviation from the norm (i.e., formal<br />
institutions). Close and complex links between<br />
and overlaps of formal and informal spheres exist<br />
in all political systems. This makes it rather<br />
difficult to distinguish clearly between formal<br />
and informal (loc.cit. 11), a factor that has to be<br />
kept in mind when investigating decision-making<br />
processes. Governance analysis reveals the<br />
specific strength of the formal-informal modes<br />
of a political system, as well as their interrelations,<br />
which shed light on the „real function“<br />
(KÖLLNER 2005, 27) of a political system and<br />
are therefore of eminent importance for analysis.<br />
To <strong>und</strong>erstand how a city is governed with<br />
its different policies and strategies can only be<br />
<strong>und</strong>erstood when both formal and informal rules<br />
and negotiations are analyzed (loc.cit.; see also<br />
KIRCHBERGER 2004).<br />
Informality – part of the game in<br />
the Pearl River Delta<br />
In the Pearl River Delta (PRD), a very active<br />
state has been experimenting with flexible<br />
deregulation within rigid institutional settings<br />
since the start of the reform process more than<br />
30 years ago. As a result, informality is constantly<br />
being produced, which <strong>und</strong>erlines ROY’s<br />
(2009, 826) argument that informality is located<br />
within the scope of the state rather than outside<br />
of it. Though formal political institutions mature<br />
and become increasingly effective, informality<br />
remains robust and important in Chinese socioeconomic<br />
politics (FUKUI 2000). However, informal<br />
institutions, like any socio-economic
F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 103<br />
phenomenon, have changed and have been<br />
transformed over time and space (ALTROCK<br />
2012; FUKUI 2000, 13; WAIBEL 2008).<br />
The prominence of informality in China is<br />
closely related to the country’s political culture.<br />
Thus, one rather conventional explanation<br />
why informal institutions are so pervasive in<br />
China is suggested by PYE (1985): “In most situations,<br />
whether in the party, the bureaucracy,<br />
or in nongovernmental institutions such as<br />
schools and factories, too many people are<br />
waiting in line for advancement and too few<br />
options exist for the formal procedures to do<br />
the job of selection. Therefore everyone must<br />
prudently seek guanxi ties […]. Within the<br />
Chinese bureaucracy the formal regulations<br />
tend to be overly constrictive, producing cumbersome<br />
procedures and little effective action.<br />
[…] hence the informal structures of power<br />
built through the guanxi networks often serve<br />
as the most effective way of getting the state’s<br />
business done.” In such a context, informality<br />
is mostly attributed to excessive state regulations<br />
(ROY/ALSAYYAD 2004, 13). Doubtlessly,<br />
the fact that the PRD has one of the most complex<br />
administrative systems in the world with<br />
multiple jurisdictions is conducive to such<br />
kinds of informality (ENRIGHT et al. 2005, 233).<br />
A more comprehensive analysis of specific<br />
Chinese informal institutions made by social<br />
scientists over the last three decades has revealed<br />
a multiplicity of factors explaining their<br />
origin (KIRCHBERGER 2004, 17), including:<br />
– The particular cultural path of institutions<br />
based on the Confucian tradition and the political<br />
culture formed by the socialist revolution.<br />
One example of the historical continuities<br />
is the duality between the formal Confucian<br />
respect for thoughtful, selfless, and<br />
public-minded manners on the one hand and<br />
the self-seeking, interest-driven, and exchange-mediated<br />
behavior in actual life on<br />
the other.<br />
– The importance of interpersonal relationships,<br />
so-called guanxi. Political influence is<br />
applied through subtle, culturally sanctioned<br />
behavior by way of exchanges of favors and<br />
repayment of commitment (FUKUI 2000,<br />
15 f.).<br />
– There is a lack of a rule-of-law tradition.<br />
– The closely interlinked party-state structure,<br />
which creates structural latitude. It is characterized<br />
by the parallel party-state structure,<br />
which allows for and encompasses diverse<br />
and often opaque linkages between vertical<br />
and horizontal lines of authorities (HEBERER/<br />
SCHUBERT 2004; HEILMANN 2004).<br />
However, the list might be arbitrarily continued.<br />
What is distinctive in the way informality<br />
is used in China is that there is an amalgamation<br />
of formalities and – importantly – a pragmatic<br />
use of informal relationships. Informality will<br />
most likely not disappear altogether. On the<br />
contrary, it is the way in which informality is<br />
practiced that changes over time.<br />
Apparently, the Chinese state and its local representatives<br />
at various levels engage in an ambiguous<br />
set of practices concerning the role of<br />
informality. ALTROCK/SCHOON (2009) coined<br />
the term “conceded informality” for this phenomenon.<br />
The term emphasizes the pro-active<br />
state that tolerates informal practices where<br />
they are functional (see also WAIBEL 2008;<br />
2009; WAIBEL/GRAVERT 2009). This cooptation<br />
of informal structures to serve formal government<br />
has a long tradition in China. Conceded<br />
informality seeks to abandon the dichotomy between<br />
formal and informal. LEAF (2005) speaks<br />
of cooperative governance between formal and<br />
informal structures, for example. The extent to<br />
which informality is tolerated, used, or promoted<br />
depends on a variety of determinants such as<br />
the power of the state to formulate regulations<br />
and policies; the availability of resources in the<br />
public sector; global, national, and regional<br />
economic competitiveness; and global influences<br />
on socio-cultural aspects. Specific patterns<br />
and attitudes dealing with informality in<br />
China, and in the PRD in particular, have been<br />
identified by ALTROCK/WAIBEL (2010) and<br />
SCHOON (2010):<br />
– The state “fights” informality, when its major<br />
political objectives are threatened.<br />
– The state “tolerates” informality, when it<br />
serves development.<br />
– The state “promotes” informality, when it<br />
produces new strategic knowledge.<br />
– The state “utilizes” informality, when flexible<br />
guiding principles serve as political strategy.
104 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
This listing shows that the state and its local<br />
representatives take a tactical approach in using<br />
their position as rule-setters. For example, they<br />
may accept informal bottom-up initiatives and<br />
subsequently formalize them, e.g., as an adequate<br />
response to newly emerging problems or<br />
niches, or they can forbid them and, as a consequence,<br />
ban informal institutions. Another more<br />
simple reason for informality in the PRD can be<br />
the lack of state power to efficiently filter<br />
through all spheres of institutions, markets, and<br />
society from the very beginning of the transitional<br />
process (ALTROCK/WAIBEL 2010, 12).<br />
The role of informality in China has wide implications<br />
for urban governance, hence the way<br />
economic restructuring and the accompanied<br />
reproduction of urban areas. Flexible and experimental,<br />
testing and learning arrangements<br />
are expected to being applied by local state and<br />
private (i.e. companies) actors for the implementation<br />
of economic restructuring policies.<br />
Changing urban governance in<br />
the Pearl River Delta<br />
In China, urban governance is characterized by<br />
a high degree of state, especially local government,<br />
control in urban policies (NG/TANG 2004,<br />
175). Since the implementation of market reforms<br />
in the late 1970s, the central government<br />
does no longer exercise an all-embracing topdown<br />
control over economy and society<br />
(CHAN/HU 2004, 10; NG/TANG 2004, 175; XU/<br />
WANG 2002, 250). In fact, economic, administrative,<br />
and fiscal decentralization has taken<br />
place throughout China since the start of the reform<br />
process, although politically, there has<br />
been no significant sign of devolution (CHIEN<br />
2008, 3). The combination of new market elements<br />
and decentralized state apparatus has offered<br />
ab<strong>und</strong>ant flexibility especially for local<br />
governments in pursuing extrabudgetary revenues<br />
to facilitate entrepreneurialism in urban<br />
development (WU 2002, 1075). Though still<br />
strong, the predominant role of the central state<br />
has been softened in many aspects of urban<br />
change, new players from the private sector appeared<br />
in shaping the urban landscape. The<br />
prevalent mono-player arena has changed towards<br />
a multiplayer arena with multifaceted interactions<br />
of central and local governments, domestic<br />
and foreign investors and businesses (HE<br />
et al. 2006, 432). All in all, the transition from<br />
planned to market economy, the policy of open-<br />
ing up and increasing integration into the world<br />
market, as well as learning processes and capacity<br />
building within the country have directed<br />
changes in the control, provision, and coordination<br />
mechanisms over time (WUTTKE 2009,<br />
11). In other words, the gradual implementation<br />
of the reform process in China is causing constant<br />
change in the “rules of the game”. This<br />
implies changing governance arrangements, as<br />
well.<br />
In particular, local governments, i.e. municipal<br />
and urban district governments, have become<br />
key actors of economic and urban regulation<br />
processes. Increased competition between<br />
cities vying to attract companies and investments,<br />
but also environmental degradation and<br />
social and spatial fragmentation are significant<br />
challenges for China’s metropolises. This in<br />
turn requires the constant adaptation of urban<br />
development strategies. The increased importance<br />
of local governments and of private companies<br />
for overall economic welfare has<br />
strengthened their role in decision-making. The<br />
autonomy allows them – to a certain degree –<br />
to <strong>und</strong>ertake independent planning, political<br />
decisions, as well as legislative and executive<br />
governmental functions. Moreover, despite its<br />
function as regulatory instance, the local state<br />
authorities have gained responsibility in the<br />
promotion of local economic growth and, for<br />
the first time, had to apply location policies of<br />
their own to lure companies and capital. This<br />
forces them to involve stakeholders, their<br />
needs and aspirations and thus adapt a demandside<br />
approach guiding of their locational policies.<br />
How this rather customer-oriented approach<br />
is implemented will be shown in the<br />
subsequent section of this paper.<br />
The realignment of state, market and society with<br />
a changing role of local governments has been<br />
explained by different authors as the local state<br />
incrementally following the logic of economicentrepreneurial<br />
action (cf. “autonomous local<br />
governments”, LAQUIAN 2005; “local state corporatism”,<br />
OI 1992, 1995; “entrepreneurial city”,<br />
JESSOP/SUM 2000; WU 2002, 2003; WU et al.<br />
2007; “local developmental state”, ZHU 2004).<br />
Case study of Guangzhou Science City<br />
Methodology<br />
The integrated framework of urban governance<br />
developed by DIGAETANO/STROM (2003) has
F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 105<br />
been applied to the case study of the Guangzhou<br />
Science City (GSC) development and its<br />
locational policies. Concretely, how the reproduction<br />
of this urban area and its locational<br />
policies are governed in order to enforce economic<br />
restructuring is analyzed by looking at<br />
the relationships and interactions between different<br />
actors and stakeholders in the public and<br />
private sectors (governing relations, in the terminology<br />
of DiGaetano/Strom), the way decisions<br />
are made (governing logic), the impact of<br />
key decision-makers, and their political objectives.<br />
The analysis is based on qualitative, semi-structured<br />
interviews conducted in 2009 and 2010.<br />
Two main groups of interviewees were selected<br />
for interviews. The first, stakeholders, consisted<br />
of individuals with a potential stake in the development<br />
and locational policies of GSC, such<br />
as members of governmental bodies, planning<br />
bureaus, companies located within GSC, and<br />
residents, among them villagers affected by<br />
eviction, living in the area of interest; the second,<br />
experts, was made up of professionals<br />
such as academic staff and planning experts that<br />
were not directly involved in locational policies,<br />
but have in-depth knowledge regarding the<br />
case study. Interviews with experts proofed to<br />
be especially valuable for qualifying the wider<br />
economic, political context. Altogether, 35 interviews<br />
were conducted; of which eleven with<br />
experts and 24 with stakeholders. The research<br />
is complemented by an intensive review of governmental<br />
documents, newspaper articles and<br />
scientific literature.<br />
According to our research experience, in China,<br />
governance is frequently equated with participation<br />
in the realm of civil society. Having been<br />
warned that in China, research in the field of<br />
governance is often mis<strong>und</strong>erstood as looking<br />
for incidences of corruption, we frequently used<br />
the term “urban management” doing interviews,<br />
particularly when talking to political<br />
leaders.<br />
Guangzhou Science City – a symbol of<br />
economic upgrading<br />
Guangzhou Science City (GSC) has been selected<br />
as a showcase project, which represents a<br />
spatial cluster of the higher value-added sector<br />
and stands for the attempt to upgrade the local<br />
economy (HE 2006, 205; WANG/HUANG 2007,<br />
18). From an analytical governance perspec-<br />
tive, its development is rather innovative. In<br />
contrast to earlier developments, it is the result<br />
of a comprehensive urban development strategy<br />
and therefore represents much more than a<br />
mere economic entity with high-tech focus: The<br />
formerly strict division of industrial and urban<br />
residential and commercial areas is loosened.<br />
Besides building a new administrative center as<br />
well as living area, the entire district, in which<br />
GSC is located, has been planned as comprehensive<br />
urban environment to become an integral<br />
part of the whole metropolis. Moreover, as<br />
part of the Plan for the reform and development<br />
of the Pearl River Delta (2008-2020) promoting<br />
the restructuring of the PRD’s economic<br />
base, GSC is a very illustrative example for the<br />
interplay of economic upgrading and comprehensive<br />
urban development strategies.<br />
Located in the eastern part of Guangzhou and<br />
comprising a total planning area of nearly 45<br />
km 2 , GSC constitutes the linchpin of the<br />
Guangzhou high-tech industrial development<br />
zone (GHIDZ). As part of Guangzhou’s Urban<br />
development concept plan established in 2000,<br />
the city’s east is intended to serve as a center for<br />
high-tech development (XU/YEH 2003). The<br />
area has been strategically important for<br />
Guangzhou’s economy since the early 1980s,<br />
encompassing four national-level special economic<br />
areas (Guangzhou Economic and Technological<br />
Development District GETDD,<br />
Guangzhou Hi-Tech Industrial Development<br />
Zone GHIDZ, Guangzhou Free Trade Zone<br />
GFTZ, and Guangzhou Export Processing Zone<br />
GEPZ). These economic areas were merged <strong>und</strong>er<br />
a single joint administration in 2002 and renamed<br />
the Guangzhou Development District<br />
(GDD) (SCHRÖDER/WAIBEL 2010, 70).<br />
As priority project for economic upgrading<br />
along the value chain, GSC is supposed to<br />
develop into a flagship high-tech park with a<br />
focus on information technology, bioscence,<br />
pharmaceutical, and environmental industries.<br />
Besides building a new center and a residential<br />
area, the area as a whole is planned as a comprehensive<br />
urban environment, including the<br />
provision of the social, educational, and administrative<br />
infrastructure elements required to<br />
make it an integral part of the overall city (HE<br />
2006, 205). In this regard, it not only serves as<br />
a location for the attraction of knowledge-intensive<br />
companies, but is also designed to attract a<br />
qualified white-collar workforce to work and<br />
live in this area. Further, it is anticipated that
106 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
GSC will relieve the core city and contribute to<br />
a more polycentric urban development.<br />
Governance in the development phase of GSC<br />
The analysis of governing relations, governing<br />
logic, political objectives, and key stakeholders<br />
in the development of GSC reveals a mode of<br />
strongly (local) government-led initiation as<br />
well as implementation. However, needs and<br />
interests of companies but also of inhabitants<br />
have been increasingly considered. This has not<br />
taken place via direct participation but in panels<br />
and mostly informal exchange where experts,<br />
selected elites, and companies take part in. Surveys<br />
served to give insights on the needs of local<br />
population, which were included in the<br />
planning process (TANG et al. 2008; WUTTKE et<br />
al. 2010).<br />
Guangzhou municipality and its relevant administrative<br />
bodies already initiated the project<br />
of GSC in 1998, led the master planning and selected<br />
the site. Together with district-level government<br />
bodies they were responsible for project<br />
implementation. However, key decisions<br />
have been finalized by high officials (on municipal<br />
and district level), whose personal development<br />
visions apparently influenced the<br />
planning proposals. A common occurrence in<br />
China’s urban planning is the involvement of so<br />
called experts as consultants from outsourced<br />
or privatized urban management research institutes<br />
or planning bureaus to aid in shaping the<br />
economic reforms (LEAF/HOU 2006; TANG et al.<br />
2008; WONG et al. 2006). Accordingly, Chinese<br />
research and planning institutes were directly<br />
approached by governing bodies to participate<br />
in functional planning and design of the master<br />
plans for GSC.<br />
Besides municipal and district planning departments,<br />
private and international planning bureaus<br />
were allowed to participate in the development<br />
process as well. This is a new phenomenon<br />
as a result of strategic planning,<br />
established in Guangzhou in the year 2000.<br />
Strategic planning has emerged as an important<br />
tool to respond quickly to the development and<br />
control needs of local governments (LEAF/HOU<br />
2006, 569; SCHRÖDER/WAIBEL 2010, 74). It has<br />
been arisen from initiatives by local municipal<br />
governments supplementing conventional master<br />
planning which was considered as static and<br />
inadequate to respond to rapid socio-economic<br />
and urban spatial change. The Guangzhou Concept<br />
Plan 2000 was the first strategic tool for<br />
urban development implemented in China<br />
(WANG et al. 2001, 5; WU/ZHANG 2007, 719).<br />
This procedure is a perfect example of experimental<br />
governance in China. First tested in<br />
Guangzhou and subsequently Hangzhou (Concept<br />
Plan of Hangzhou), these two plans are<br />
now being followed by other cities in China.<br />
Strategic planning as it is <strong>und</strong>erstood and practiced<br />
in China is <strong>und</strong>ertaken to support localized<br />
economic targets in line with attracting and<br />
Fig. 2: Changing involvement of key stakeholders during the development process of<br />
Guangzhou Science City<br />
Source: own design
F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 107<br />
guiding capital investment. It addresses more<br />
flexible aspects of urbanization such as development<br />
directions, which are soft, rather vague<br />
formulated as future targets in urban development<br />
and land use. These directions are beyond<br />
what is considered by the physical planning orientation<br />
of formal statutory planning (LEAF/<br />
HOU 2006, 569).<br />
Moreover, semi-private or special purpose associations<br />
have been involved to take over<br />
functions that were formerly the prerogative of<br />
the administration; most importantly in the development<br />
of GSC these are investment consultancies.<br />
They not only served as negotiation<br />
part in the realm of the district government<br />
when it came to relocation processes of villages<br />
located within the planning bo<strong>und</strong>aries. They<br />
also have close relationships with companies<br />
located in the area. They share believes and experiences<br />
with local governments and give suggestions<br />
due to their in depth knowledge about<br />
companies’ and their workforces’ needs. Together<br />
with the governments’ own mostly informal<br />
exchanges with companies and with overseas<br />
experiences, these suggestions form the<br />
basis of decision-making processes in the case<br />
of developing GSC. Face-to-face communication,<br />
e.g. during regular meetings within companies<br />
or symposiums with businesses, is used<br />
to learn about changing needs and demands of<br />
companies, workforce and inhabitants (mostly<br />
white collar). Collected needs and aspirations<br />
are condensed and presented to the local People’s<br />
Congress (PC) and the Chinese People’s<br />
Source: WAIBEL/SCHRÖDEr 2009<br />
Political Consultative Conference (CPPCC) to<br />
be discussed and revised. Accordingly, planning<br />
strategies are constantly revised and adapted.<br />
In sum, though not formal involved in the development<br />
process, non-state actors such as experts,<br />
companies and white-collar workforce<br />
are apparently indirectly involved building-up<br />
informal arrangements with governing bodies<br />
and therefore influencing changing urban development<br />
strategies (see Fig. 2). However, these<br />
informal arrangements are open to a small group<br />
of selected people, only. For example, the ordinary<br />
population of the villages located within<br />
Luogang District has not been included: About<br />
60,000 of them had been relocated in the course<br />
of the development of GSC since 2004. However,<br />
participation was limited to a survey on their<br />
housing conditions <strong>und</strong>ertaken on behalf on the<br />
management committee as well as to exclusionary<br />
negotiations with the village heads.<br />
All in all, it can be said, that the deliberate use<br />
of informal arrangements in the development of<br />
GSC served local officials to learn from exogenous<br />
experiences via interactions with foreign,<br />
returning overseas Chinese, and domestic investors.<br />
In this regard, investment, especially<br />
foreign direct investment can not only be regarded<br />
as a driver for economic growth but also<br />
an important channel of knowledge diffusion<br />
for changing urban governance processes<br />
(CHIEN/ZHAO 2008). There is a close connection<br />
between urban development strategies and<br />
locational policies of GSC since the compre-<br />
Fig. 3: Residential-, leisure- and work-spaces in Gouangzhou Science City
108 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
hensive development approach adopted for establishing<br />
GSC can be viewed as part of an<br />
overall strategy to enhance the area’s attractiveness<br />
for investors and white-collar people to<br />
work and live in GSC.<br />
Locational policies and the role of informality<br />
in Guangzhou Science City<br />
The raison d’être of special economic areas in<br />
China is to attract investors and therefore to<br />
gain revenues. In times of economic restructuring,<br />
it no longer suffices for the management<br />
bodies to offer a fenced mono-functional industrial<br />
area, as was the case 20 years ago. Nowadays,<br />
the message of economic upgrading and<br />
advancement along the value chain is the most<br />
important driver in locational policies. As a result,<br />
clean and liveable urban environments<br />
with a lot of greenery and flagship architecture<br />
are introduced to a highly competitive market.<br />
This is especially true for GSC. Here, locational<br />
policies can be seen as an interplay of three<br />
important tools: (1) hard incentive schemes; (2)<br />
a comprehensive approach in designing the<br />
physical outline of the area; and (3) soft incentive<br />
schemes. Hard incentive schemes are<br />
means from the classical toolbox of economic<br />
development and investment attraction. In<br />
GSC, these include the provision of technical<br />
infrastructure such as roads, gas, electricity,<br />
etc., economic incentives such as tax reductions<br />
and tax holidays, low or no land use fees, including<br />
discounted rentals, low energy costs,<br />
and physical infrastructure such as an incubator<br />
center for start-up companies to rent out lab and<br />
office space or a special f<strong>und</strong>ing program for attracting<br />
start-up companies.<br />
GSC is planned for development into a comprehensive<br />
urban area. It is intended that “urban<br />
liveability” and “quality of life” will be created<br />
by the integration of various urban functions<br />
specifically, housing, education, leisure and<br />
amenities, and generous provision of greenery<br />
and space in general (Fig. 3). The simple assumption<br />
behind this new approach in regard to<br />
the physical outline of GSC is that the more<br />
qualified (white-collar and presumably creative)<br />
workforce working in knowledge-intensive<br />
companies and living in the area is expected<br />
to have different needs and aspirations concerning<br />
the urban environment than lowerqualified<br />
(blue-collar) people working in laborintensive<br />
industries.<br />
Eventually, soft incentive schemes are formed<br />
aro<strong>und</strong> different informal, flexible, and trustbuilding<br />
services provided by the zone management<br />
and semi-private or special purpose associations<br />
such as investment consultancies. In<br />
GSC, these include openness regarding information<br />
policies towards companies, pragmatism,<br />
service orientation, and particularly<br />
network promotion activities. The latter encompasses<br />
various different layers of communication<br />
between companies, between companies<br />
and organizations (e.g., chambers of commerce,<br />
investment consultancies), and between companies<br />
and the government that serve to enhance<br />
relationships and knowledge diffusion. This<br />
mainly takes place in informal meetings at<br />
lunch, dinner, during breaks at conferences or<br />
club events such as a yearly golf tournament organized<br />
by the Guangzhou Multinational Corporation<br />
Club (MNCC). The primary aim of the<br />
network promotion activities is to increase<br />
communication between companies with the<br />
aim of fostering some kind of “innovative milieu”.<br />
Our research fo<strong>und</strong> that this multi-layered,<br />
complex net also serves another important<br />
purpose: It allows the management body to get<br />
information on the needs and aspirations of<br />
companies and their workforce. This information<br />
gained by interaction-based informality is<br />
highly appreciated, because it allows development<br />
strategies and location policies to be frequently<br />
adjusted in order to remain attractive<br />
for the companies. In this respect, learning<br />
processes may be <strong>und</strong>erstood here as “learning<br />
by interacting” (LIEFNER 2008). Such learning<br />
processes are evidently crucial drivers for the<br />
flexible adaptation of governance processes towards<br />
economic restructuring (SCHRÖDER/WAI-<br />
BEL 2010, 78).<br />
A soft incentive feature that may be less publicized,<br />
but was often mentioned during our interviews<br />
with companies is the zone management’s<br />
pragmatism and service orientation. In<br />
this context, pragmatism means a flexible approach<br />
in dealing with (formal) regularities. A<br />
striking example for this is the management<br />
body’s pragmatic dealing with registration policies.<br />
Apparently, enterprises are not necessarily<br />
obliged to be physically located within the area<br />
of GSC itself. Apparently, it is sufficient just to<br />
be classified as a high-tech company by the<br />
government to enjoy the zone’s preferential<br />
policies. Furthermore, the zone management of<br />
GSC has a high reputation for its service orientation,<br />
efficiency, and professionalism, and tries<br />
to resolve any issues arising for companies
F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 109<br />
within a few days. Further services include<br />
training courses for start-up companies in the<br />
fields of business development, tax regulations,<br />
and acquisition of financial support. Apparently,<br />
the specific, increasingly institutionalized interaction<br />
between management body and the<br />
companies over time in the area of GSC has<br />
contributed to – in terms of SCHAMP (2003, 151)<br />
– time- and space-specific institutional arrangements<br />
that rest on path dependencies but at the<br />
same time have the potential of establishing<br />
new structures for action.<br />
Our research reveals that comprehensive urban<br />
planning and soft incentive schemes are becoming<br />
more and more important in the course<br />
of economic upgrading, and that these factors<br />
can provide a decisive local advantage in competition<br />
with other spatial economic entities.<br />
This has been confirmed by interviews with<br />
stakeholders and experts. Hard incentive<br />
schemes have become increasingly ubiquitous<br />
among special economic areas all over China,<br />
and have therefore become less significant as a<br />
location factor. Anyway, the significance of<br />
these zones decreased after China’s WTO entry<br />
was followed by the gradual reduction of preferential<br />
policies and economic incentives. Certainly,<br />
the fierce competition between special<br />
economic areas has promoted the deliberate use<br />
of informal arrangements and therefore higher<br />
flexibility regarding the governance of economic<br />
entities in China.<br />
Conclusion<br />
It has been illustrated that the shift from laborintensive<br />
towards higher value-added and capital-intensive<br />
industries is actively promoted by<br />
national, provincial, and local governing bodies<br />
in China’s “factory of the world”, the Pearl River<br />
Delta. The upgrading process apparently requires<br />
new urban development strategies and<br />
locational policies as well as innovative governance<br />
constellations. In the tradition of the Chinese<br />
transitional process, which is based on experimental<br />
approaches, informality is being<br />
produced and applied in a flexible way. By analyzing<br />
the development of GSC and its locational<br />
policies, this paper has argued that interaction-based<br />
informality is used as a tool of<br />
flexibility as well as of experimental policies attracting<br />
knowledge-intensive industries and a<br />
highly educated workforce. The pursuit of competiveness<br />
and the importance of learning are<br />
immanent features of this process. Since hard<br />
incentives, such as the provision of a reliable<br />
technical infrastructure, are no longer unique<br />
selling propositions, new strategies have to be<br />
identified as means of distinction. The management<br />
body of GSC is applying a wide range of<br />
rather informal strategies in its development<br />
strategies and location policies. This is apparently<br />
happening despite a very clear and highly<br />
transparent regulatory framework guiding investments<br />
and development procedures.<br />
Thus, the competitiveness of GSC results to a<br />
large extent from high flexibility and service<br />
orientation towards incoming companies, mostly<br />
negotiated in informal interactions. Here, informality<br />
as a mode of flexibility serves as a<br />
strategy in locational policies to create a local<br />
competitive edge. Further, informality is used<br />
as tool for testing and learning. The selective involvement<br />
of private actors and stakeholders in<br />
the development and locational policies of GSC<br />
has been cited as an example. So far, this informal<br />
procedure has mostly taken place via particularistic<br />
and personalized exchanges or, to<br />
use the terminology of DIGAETANO/STROM<br />
(2003), through a rather clientelistic governance<br />
mode. If this approach proves successful<br />
in the long run, we may safely expect it to be<br />
formalized, and then maybe even to become<br />
less selective. This would imply a change of<br />
governance mode towards non-exclusive<br />
arrangements.<br />
Moreover, the use of informality produces new<br />
strategic knowledge in terms of comprehensive<br />
urban development as well as in terms of upgrading<br />
strategies towards a knowledge-based<br />
economy. In this way, the management body of<br />
Guangzhou Science City deliberately uses informality<br />
as a mode of learning. All in all, we<br />
would like to reiterate the important point that it<br />
is the hybrid interconnectedness between informal<br />
and formal practices that makes the location<br />
policies of special economic entities successful.<br />
Therefore, simplistic connotations such<br />
as that of the formal-informal divide, or the implicit<br />
idea of formality as the norm and informality<br />
as a deviation from the norm, are obsolete<br />
when dealing with current urban realities in<br />
China and elsewhere.<br />
Looking at the development of governance and<br />
informality over time in the course of China’s<br />
reform period, it can be stated that in the early<br />
stage of the transitional process, status-related
110 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
informality was widely used as an alternative or<br />
substitute for an inadequate or lacking legislative<br />
framework and non-existing local capacity<br />
(subsumed here <strong>und</strong>er the concept of “institutional<br />
gaps”). In the further course of the reform<br />
period, during the advanced transitional<br />
process, however, informality may be more and<br />
more regarded as a complement to formal<br />
arrangements and to formal ways of interaction<br />
(ALTROCK 2011; WAIBEL 2009).<br />
Linking governance with the notion of informality<br />
reveals the importance of institutions<br />
within the complex and highly dynamic urban<br />
environment of China’s transitional process. In<br />
order to add to the picture of urban governance<br />
and informality in urban China, research on<br />
other policy fields as well as on further spatial<br />
and sectoral arenas is no doubt indispensable.<br />
Grasping informality in China by means of an<br />
analytical governance framework such as the<br />
model of DiGaetano/Strom is certainly a challenge.<br />
First of all, it has to be reflected whether<br />
such a model, developed in a Western context,<br />
is appropriate for analyzing informal processes<br />
in China. Certainly, this framework has to be<br />
adapted to the situation in China. The field research<br />
and subsequent application has shown<br />
advantageous and disadvantageous aspects. Di-<br />
Gaetano/Strom’s model of urban governance is<br />
enticing because of its comprehensive scope,<br />
which integrates three middle-range theories,<br />
i.e., structuralism, culturalism, and rational<br />
choice. But this comprehensive approach calls<br />
for the consideration of a multitude of aspects<br />
(e.g. structures and processes, culture, institutions,<br />
actor-relations) in urban affairs. In this<br />
way, it reveals challenges in research that might<br />
finally lead to a lack of theoretical and empirical<br />
depth. Furthermore, the specific case of China<br />
reveals characteristics such as the political<br />
system (socialism with Chinese characters), the<br />
important role of personal networks (guanxi),<br />
the parallel party-state-system, that require particular<br />
consideration when analyzing urban<br />
governance in China. All of these particularities<br />
are difficult to cover using the DiGaetano/Strom<br />
model which shows the limits of its<br />
applicability.<br />
However, we should highlight the fact that the<br />
model also has its merits. For example, its<br />
breadth proved to be a distinct advantage, because<br />
it helps to embrace complexities in urban<br />
affairs. These complexities are due to the plurality<br />
and often opaqueness of national, provin-<br />
cial, municipal, and even district strategies as<br />
well as the multi-faceted relations between the<br />
government, the corporate sector, and the<br />
emerging civil society, to name but a few challenges.<br />
The model grasps the major and complex<br />
influences affecting urban affairs. Each approach<br />
alone would not be sufficient for mapping<br />
the dynamic interdependencies and<br />
interrelations between structures (and processes),<br />
culture, and actors. At the same time, the<br />
model reduces the fuzziness of concepts such as<br />
governance and informality, whose ambiguous<br />
nature is certainly a challenge regarding conceptualization<br />
and empirical operationalization.<br />
Also, aspects of temporality are included within<br />
the framework, particularly in the structural<br />
context layer. These merits are especially important<br />
for analyzing urban governance within<br />
the highly dynamic urban environment of transitional<br />
China.<br />
Notes<br />
1 In comparison, the average GERD (gross domestic expenditure<br />
on R&D) in the European Union in 2007<br />
was 1.8 %, in Germany and Japan 2.5 %, 3.5 % respectively.<br />
2 The division between informal institutions and political<br />
culture is often misleading. In this respect, we propose<br />
to follow the <strong>und</strong>erstanding of KIRCHBERGER<br />
(2004, 11). According to her, all observable regular but<br />
not formally codified behavior patterns that apply to<br />
interaction between different actors are considered “informal<br />
institutions”. In contrast, behavior patterns that<br />
are not directly observable, internalized moral concepts,<br />
and individual socializations are considered<br />
“political culture” (ibid.). Following this line of argumentation,<br />
the widespread guanxi as the traditional<br />
network of personal relations in China would be related<br />
to political culture whereas a not formalized negotiation<br />
process over political affairs would relate to informal<br />
institutions.<br />
References<br />
ALTROCK, U. (2012): Conceptualizing informality: Some<br />
thoughts on the way towards generalization. In McFarlane,<br />
C./ Waibel, M. (Eds.): Urban Informalities: Reflections<br />
on the Formal and Informal. Farnham. (forthcoming).<br />
ALTROCK, U./PILLATH, C.-H./WAIBEL, M. (2008): Governance<br />
over time: Spatial Differentiation and temporal<br />
change of urban development and redevelopment in a<br />
context of multiple transitions and informal growth in<br />
the PRD. DFG Priority Programme 1233: “Megacities -<br />
Megachallenge: Informal Dynamics of Global Change”.<br />
(Unpublished research project proposal).
F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 111<br />
ALTROCK, U./SCHOON, S. (2009): The Governance of Urban<br />
Regeneration in Southern China. Liverpool. (Paper<br />
presented at the AESOP Conference, 15-18 July 2009,<br />
Liverpool, UK).<br />
ALTROCK, U./WAIBEL, M. (2010): The governance of<br />
spatial and economic restructuring. Informal dynamics<br />
of the maturing mega-city. DFG Priority Programme<br />
1233: “Megacities-Megachallenge: Informal Dynamics<br />
of Global Change”. (Unpublished research project proposal).<br />
BENZ, A./LÜTZ, S./SCHIMANK, U./SIMONIS, G. (2007):<br />
Einleitung. In: dies. (Hrsg.): Handbuch Governance.<br />
Theoretische Gr<strong>und</strong>lagen <strong>und</strong> empirische Anwendungsfelder.<br />
Wiesbaden, 9-26.<br />
CHAN, R. C. K./HU, Y. (2004): Urban governance. A theoretical<br />
review and an empirical study. In: Asian Geographer,<br />
(23)1-2, 5-18.<br />
CHIEN, S.-S. (2008): Urban/regional governance, Chinese<br />
style. A perspective of asymmetric decentralization.<br />
Berlin. (International Essay Competition and Workshop<br />
on „Collective Identities, Governance and Empowerment<br />
in Megacities“, Urban Planet Conference Series organized<br />
by the Irmgard-Coninx-Fo<strong>und</strong>ation in cooperation<br />
with the Humboldt-University and the WZB, 11th –<br />
16th June 2008, Berlin).<br />
DANIELS, P.W. (2004): Urban challenges: the formal and<br />
informal economies in megacities. In: Cities, (21)6, 501-<br />
511.<br />
DIGAETANO, A./STROM, E. (2003): Comparative urban<br />
governance. An integrated approach. In: Urban Affairs<br />
Review, (38)3, 356-395.<br />
ENRIGHT, M. J./SCOTT, E. E./ CHANG, K.-M. (2005): Regional<br />
powerhouse. The Greater Pearl River Delta and<br />
the rise of China. Singapore.<br />
FAINSTEIN, S./CAMPBELL, S. (2002): Introduction. Theories<br />
of urban development and their implications for policy<br />
and planning. In: Fainstein, S./Campbell, S. (Eds.):<br />
Readings in urban theory. Malden a.o., 1-15.<br />
FEWSMITH, J. (2004): Promoting the scientific development<br />
concept. In: China Leadership Monitor, Summer<br />
2004, (11), 1-10.<br />
FUKUI, H. (2000): Introduction. On the significance of<br />
informal politics. In: Dittmer, Li/ Fukui, H./ Lee, P.N.S.<br />
(Eds.): Informal politics in East Asia. Cambridge a.o., 1-<br />
19.<br />
Guangdong Statistical Yearbook (2010): National economic<br />
accounts. Internet: http://www.gdstats.gov.cn/tjnj/<br />
e3.htm (3. 8. 2011).<br />
HASSINK, R. (2005):0 Guest editorial: The restructuring<br />
of old industrial areas in Europe and Asia. In: Environment<br />
and Planning A, (37), 571-580.<br />
HE, S./LI, Z./WU, F. (2006): Transformation of the Chinese<br />
city, 1995-2005. Geographical perspectives and geographers’<br />
contributions. In: China Information, (20)3,<br />
429-456.<br />
HE, Y.-G. (2006). Guangzhou Science Park. An ideal<br />
place for “Two Suitable”. The planning and experience<br />
in construction management of Guangzhou Science<br />
Park. In: National Territorial Construction Bureau of<br />
Guangzhou Development District (Ed.): 20 years in<br />
Guangzhou Development Zone. Guangzhou, 204-214<br />
(Chinese).<br />
HEBERER, T./SCHUBERT, G. (2008): Politische Partizipation<br />
<strong>und</strong> Regimelegitimität in der VR China. Band I: Der<br />
urbane Raum. Wiesbaden.<br />
HEILMANN, S. (2004): Das politische System der Volksrepublik<br />
China. Wiesbaden. (2. Aufl.)<br />
JESSOP, B./SUM, N.-L. (2000): An entrepreneurial city in<br />
action: Hong Kong’s emerging strategies in and for (inter)urban<br />
competition. In: Urban Studies, (37)12, 2287 -<br />
2313.<br />
JESSOP, B. (1995): The regulation approach, governance<br />
and post-fordism. Alternative perspectives on economic<br />
and political change? In: Economy and Society, 24(3),<br />
307-333.<br />
KIRCHBERGER, S. (2004): Informelle Regeln der Politik<br />
in China <strong>und</strong> Taiwan. Hamburg.<br />
KOOIMAN, J. (2005): Governing as governance. In:<br />
Schuppert, G.F. (Hrsg.): Governance-Forschung. Vergewisserung<br />
über Stand <strong>und</strong> Perspektiven. Baden-Baden,<br />
149-172.<br />
KUHN, R. (2009a): Guangdong. Re-envisioning<br />
Guangzhou. Internet: http://www.businessweek.com/<br />
globalbiz/content/jul2009/gb2009076_009429.htm<br />
(12.4.2010).<br />
KUHN, R. (2009b): Guangdong visions. A talk with<br />
Wang Yang. Internet: http://www.businessweek.com/<br />
globalbiz/content/jun2009/gb2009065_691758.htm<br />
(12.4. 2010).<br />
KUHN, R. (2009c): Guangdong visions. Forging China’s<br />
future.Internet:http://www.businessweek.com/globalbiz/<br />
content/aug2009/gb2009084_539590.htm (12.4. 2010).<br />
KUHN, R. (2009d) Guangdong visions. Responding to<br />
the crisis. Internet: http://www.businessweek.com/<br />
globalbiz/content/jun2009/gb20090615_39380.htm<br />
(12.4. 2010).<br />
KUHN, R. (2009e) Guangdong visions. The way forward.<br />
Internet: http://www.businessweek.com/globalbiz/<br />
content/oct2009/gb2009101_302976.htm (12.4. 2010).<br />
LAQUIAN, A. A. (2005): Beyond metropolis. The planning<br />
and governance of Asia’s mega-urban regions.<br />
Washington D.C./Baltimore.<br />
LEAF, M. (2005): Modernity confronts tradition. The<br />
professional planner and local corporatism in the rebuilding<br />
of China’s cities. In: Bishwapraya, S. (Ed.):<br />
Comparative Planning Cultures. New York, 91-111.<br />
LEAF, M./HOU, L. (2006): The “Third Spring” of urban<br />
planning in China: The resurrection of professional planning<br />
in the post-Mao era. In: China Information, (20)3,<br />
553-585.<br />
LIEFNER, I. (2008). Ausländische Direktinvestitionen<br />
<strong>und</strong> internationaler Wissenstransfer nach China. In:<br />
Geographische R<strong>und</strong>schau, (60)5, 4-11.<br />
LIN, G. C. S. (2001): Metropolitan development in a<br />
transitional socialist economy. Spatial restructuring in<br />
the Pearl River Delta, China. In: Urban Studies, (38)3,<br />
383-406.<br />
MAYNTZ, R. (2005): Governance Theory als fortentwickelte<br />
Steuerungstheorie? In: Schuppert, G.F. (Hrsg.):
112 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Governance-Forschung. Vergewisserung über Stand <strong>und</strong><br />
Entwicklungslinien. Bd. 1. Baden-Baden, 11-20.<br />
NDRC (National Development and Reform Commission)<br />
(2008): The outline of the plan for the reform and<br />
development of the Pearl River Delta (2008-2020). Internet:<br />
http://en.ndrc.gov.cn/ (5.8. 2009)<br />
NG, M. K./TANG, W.-S. (2004): Theorising urban planning<br />
in a transitional economy. The case of Shenzhen,<br />
People’s Republic of China. In: Town Planning Review,<br />
(75)2, 173-203.<br />
NORTH, D. C. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change,<br />
and economic performance. Cambridge/New York.<br />
OI, J. C. (1992): Fiscal reform and the economic fo<strong>und</strong>ations<br />
of local state corporatism in China. In: World<br />
Politics, (45)1, 99-126.<br />
OI, J. C. (1995): The role of the local state in China’s<br />
transitional economy. In: The China Quarterly, 144,<br />
1132-1149.<br />
PIERRE, J. (2005). Comparative urban governance. Uncovering<br />
complex causalities. In: Urban Affairs Review,<br />
(40)4, 446-462.<br />
PIERRE, J./PETERS, B. G. (2000): Governance, politics<br />
and the state. New York.<br />
PYE, L. W. (Ed.)(1985): Asian power and politics. The<br />
cultural dimension of authority. Cambridge, MA.<br />
ROY, A./ ALSAYYAD, N. (2004): Prologue/dialogue. Urban<br />
informality. Crossing borders. In: Roy, A./AlSayyad,<br />
N.: Urban informality. Transnational perspectives from<br />
the Middle East, Latin America and South Asia. Lanham/Lexington,<br />
1-6.<br />
ROY, A. (2009): The 21st-century metropolis. New geographies<br />
of theory. In: Regional Studies, (43)6, 819-830.<br />
SCHAMP, E. W. (2003): Raum, Interaktion <strong>und</strong> <strong>Institut</strong>ion.<br />
Anmerkungen zu drei Gr<strong>und</strong>perspektiven der deutschen<br />
<strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>. In: Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>,<br />
(47)3-4, 145-158.<br />
SCHOON, S. (2010): Governability, borders and urban citizenship.<br />
Part: Governability. Kassel. (Unpublished interim<br />
report, University of Kassel, Germany).<br />
SCHRÖDER, F./WAIBEL, M. (2010): Urban governance of<br />
economic upgrading processes in China. The Development<br />
of Guangzhou Science City. In: Internationales<br />
Asienforum - International Quarterly for Asian Studies,<br />
(41)1-2, 57-82.<br />
SHEN, J. (2002): Urban and regional developement in<br />
post-reform China. The case of Zhujiang Delta. In:<br />
Progress in Planning, 57, 91-140.<br />
TANG, B.-S./ WONG, S. W./ LAU, M. C. H. (2008): Social<br />
impact assessment and public participation in China. A<br />
case study of land requisition in Guangzhou. In: Environmental<br />
Impact Assessment Review, (28)1, 57-72.<br />
WAIBEL, M. (2008): Mega-urban growth, informality<br />
and the issue of governability. Towards theorising specific<br />
informal dynamics in a wider context. Berlin. (International<br />
Essay Competition and Workshop on „Col-<br />
lective Identities, Governance and Empowerment in<br />
Megacities“, Urban Planet Conference Series organized<br />
by the Irmgard-Coninx-Fo<strong>und</strong>ation in cooperation with<br />
the Humboldt-University and the WZB, 11 – 16 June<br />
2008, Berlin).<br />
WAIBEL, M. (2009): The model of the “Transitional Urban<br />
Development Cycle”. Explaining complex interrelationships<br />
between urban informality, governability, and<br />
restructuring policies. Berlin. (Workshop “Urban Development<br />
in a Globalising World – Overcoming the Formal-Informal<br />
Divide”, organized by the Irmgard-Coninx-Fo<strong>und</strong>ation<br />
in cooperation with the Humboldt-University<br />
and the WZB, 12-13 June 2009, Berlin).<br />
WAIBEL, M./GRAVERT, A. (2009): B/ordered spaces and<br />
social exclusion in Vietnam. Housing conditions of labor<br />
migrants in the face of global economic integration. In:<br />
TRIALOG - Journal for Planning and Building in the<br />
Third World, 101, 39-44.<br />
WANG, M.-H./DUAN, X.-F./TIAN, L. (2001): The practice<br />
of concept planning for the City of Guangzhou. In: Focus<br />
Report, (25)3, 5-10 (Chinese).<br />
WANG X. L./HUANG, R.-B (2007): The empirical study<br />
about Guangzhou’s science and technology originality<br />
condition. In: Science and Technology Management Research,<br />
(5), 15-19 (Chinese).<br />
WONG, S.-W./TANG, B.-S./HOREN, B. V. (2006): Strategic<br />
urban management in China. A case study of Guangzhou<br />
Development District. In: Habitat International, 30, 645-<br />
667.<br />
WU, F. (2002): China’s changing urban governance in<br />
the transition towards a more market-oriented economy.<br />
In: Urban Studies, (39)7, 1071-1093.<br />
WU, F. (2003): The (post-)socialist entrepreneurial city<br />
as a state project. Shanghai’s reglobalisation in question.<br />
In: Urban Studies, (40)9, 1673-1698.<br />
WU, F./XU, J./YEH, A. G.-O. (2007): Urban Development<br />
in post-reform China - State, market, and space.<br />
London, New York.<br />
WUTTKE, C./SCHRÖDER, F./XIAO, L. (2010): Contemporary<br />
planning issues in a pioneering city. The governance<br />
of urban redevelopment in Shenzhen, China. In: Pacific<br />
News, (33), 9-12.<br />
WUTTKE, C. (2009): Urban Governance in der Volksrepublik<br />
China. In: Geographische Zeitschrift, (97)2-3,<br />
130-150.<br />
XU, J./YEH, A. G. O. (2003): City profile (Guangzhou).<br />
In: Cities, (20)5, 361-374.<br />
XU, X./WANG, X. (2002): Characteristics of governance<br />
in China - based on the practice in the Pearl River Delta.<br />
In: Wong, K.-y./Shen, J. (Eds.): Resource management,<br />
urbanization and governance in Hong Kong and the Zhujiang<br />
Delta. Hongkong, 249-257.<br />
ZHU, J. (2004): From land use right to land development<br />
right. <strong>Institut</strong>ional change in China’s urban development.<br />
In: Urban Studies, (41)7, 1249-1267.
Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 113-120<br />
Buchbesprechungen<br />
BATHELT,HARALD/GLÜCKLER, JOHANNES:The<br />
relational economy. Geographies of knowing<br />
and learning. Oxford: Oxford University Press<br />
2011, X+298 p., £ 24,99 (paperback), £ 65,-<br />
(hardcover).<br />
Mit der „relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>“<br />
liegt seit fast einem Jahrzehnt ein neuer Entwurf<br />
<strong>für</strong> ein gr<strong>und</strong>legendes Verständnis des<br />
Wirtschaftens im Raum vor, an dem die beiden<br />
Autoren dieses Bandes an vorderster Stelle<br />
mitgewirkt haben. Das Buch folgt der verbreiteten<br />
Idee der kumulativen Publikation, nämlich<br />
die zuvor in verschiedenen (anglophonen<br />
<strong>und</strong> deutschen) Zeitschriften publizierten<br />
Gedanken <strong>und</strong> empirischen Erfahrungen der<br />
Autoren systematisiert zusammenzufassen.<br />
Hier hat es seine Berechtigung. Es wird eine<br />
Kohärenz verfügbar, die man sich davor mühsam<br />
hätte erarbeiten müssen. Obwohl beide<br />
Autoren sich auf „German research traditions“<br />
berufen (6), erheben sie seit langem international<br />
ihre Stimme in englischer Sprache. In deutscher<br />
Sprache sind ihre Positionen aus ihrem<br />
weit verbreiteten Lehrbuch (BATHELT/GLÜCK-<br />
LER 2002, 2003) bekannt.<br />
Der Gr<strong>und</strong>gedanke des Relationalen lautet: Es<br />
gibt keine (ökonomische) Handlung eines Akteurs<br />
ohne eine Beziehung zu (einem) anderen<br />
Akteur(en). Daher ist jede economic action<br />
auch zugleich eine social action. Dieser Ansatz<br />
stellt das Individuum mit seinem „praktischen“<br />
Handeln in den Mittelpunkt, ist also einer Mikroperspektive<br />
verb<strong>und</strong>en. Aus dem sozialen<br />
Handeln reproduzieren sich <strong>Institut</strong>ionen als<br />
handlungsleitende Rahmen; wird Raum hergestellt;<br />
es entstehen Prozesse, die das Lokale mit<br />
dem Globalen verbinden <strong>und</strong> zugleich an das<br />
Vorherige geb<strong>und</strong>en „pfadabhängig“ sind; <strong>und</strong><br />
es wird eine „proaktive“ Politik erforderlich<br />
(alles 6 f.). Die Vorstellung, wir lebten in einer<br />
Wissensgesellschaft, bewegt die Autoren dazu,<br />
Wissensprozesse als zentralen Gegenstand der<br />
relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> zu verstehen.<br />
Allerdings in ziemlich eklektischer Form:<br />
Dies ist – anders als der Subtitel vermuten lässt<br />
– keine umfassende Geographie des Wissens.<br />
Das Buch ist in vier Teilen aufgebaut. Teil 1<br />
legt die Gr<strong>und</strong>lagen des relationalen Denkens.<br />
Akteure handeln nur in Beziehungen zu anderen,<br />
<strong>und</strong> dieses Handeln kann man auf eine<br />
„geographische Perspektive“ (geographical<br />
lense) herunterbrechen. Unter Bezug auf Giddens<br />
Strukturationstheorie ist soziales Handeln<br />
eingebettet in Strukturen, <strong>für</strong> die <strong>Institut</strong>ionen<br />
stehen. Deren „context matters“, was zu einer<br />
eingeschränkten Handlungsfähigkeit des Akteurs<br />
in „Pfadabhängigkeit“ <strong>und</strong> Kontingenz<br />
führt (32). Wer ist der Akteur? Praktisch fühlen<br />
sich die Autoren der „geography of firms“ verb<strong>und</strong>en<br />
(vi) <strong>und</strong> diskutieren das Handeln von<br />
Unternehmern oder Unternehmen bzw. deren<br />
Experten. Welche Handlungen? Solche, die mit<br />
dem Erwerb, der Nutzung <strong>und</strong> der Verbreitung<br />
von unternehmerisch verwendbarem Wissen<br />
verb<strong>und</strong>en sind. Mit dieser Einschränkung stehen<br />
die Autoren nicht allein: Auch im Fach<br />
fehlt es an einer Empirie über das Wissen von<br />
„Nicht-Experten“ – beispielsweise von Bauern,<br />
Arbeitern, Hausfrauen, Politikern. Leider<br />
legen die Autoren eine vergleichbare Konkretisierung<br />
<strong>für</strong> den Kontext, in dem die Akteure<br />
handeln, nicht offen. Doch die empirischen<br />
Aussagen machen eine Eurozentrierung sowie<br />
den Bezug zur gegenwärtigen neoliberal geprägten<br />
„flexiblen“ <strong>Wirtschafts</strong>weise offenk<strong>und</strong>ig.<br />
Die beiden folgenden Teile des Buches vertiefen<br />
in sechs Kapiteln wichtige geographische<br />
Konstrukte sowohl konzeptionell als auch empirisch<br />
in ausführlichen Fallstudien. Teil 2 diskutiert<br />
Cluster als eine spezifisch geographische<br />
Konfiguration von Akteuren <strong>und</strong> fragt<br />
nach den Wissensprozessen in Clustern, zwischen<br />
Clustern <strong>und</strong> zu anderen (“globalen“)<br />
Orten. Teil 3 betrachtet explizit den Aufbau<br />
globaler Vernetzungen in Wissensprozessen;<br />
zuerst bei der Internationalisierung des Unternehmens<br />
sowie der Organisation globaler unternehmensinterner<br />
Wissensflüsse, dann durch<br />
Analyse der Rolle internationaler Messen als<br />
ereignisschaffende Orte, an denen Aufbau <strong>und</strong><br />
Pflege von Beziehungen zwischen Akteuren<br />
möglich werden. In diesen Kapiteln stellen die<br />
Autoren – gewissermaßen (pfad-)abhängig von<br />
ihren eigenen empirischen Erfahrungen – Fallstudien<br />
über Unternehmen aus Beratung <strong>und</strong><br />
TV sowie der Chemieindustrie vor. Das sind<br />
sehr spezifische Branchenkontexte, über die
114 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
die Autoren allerdings gelegentlich mit ihren<br />
Schlussfolgerungen weit hinausgehen.<br />
Das Buch schließt mit dem vierten Teil zur „relationalen<br />
<strong>Wirtschafts</strong>-Politik“. Das meint die<br />
Umsetzung des analytisch gewonnenen Wissens<br />
einerseits in Regionalpolitik <strong>und</strong> andererseits<br />
in Fachpolitik. Dieser Teil des Buches ist<br />
der kürzeste; er lässt den Leser einigermaßen<br />
ratlos zurück. Für die Regionalpolitik lässt sich<br />
eigentlich aus einem so strikten Konzept des<br />
individuellen Akteurs <strong>und</strong> seines „eingebetteten“<br />
Handelns wenig ableiten, was nicht längst<br />
vertieft in der Governance-Debatte zur Regionalpolitik<br />
diskutiert worden wäre. Zudem geben<br />
weder das Konzept des ex post analysierten<br />
„situativen“ Handelns noch die Fallstudien<br />
Ziele, Normen oder Ähnliches her, auf das man<br />
Handlungsempfehlungen aufbauen könnte.<br />
Der disziplinäre Ausblick bezieht sich vor allem<br />
auf Gegenstände <strong>und</strong> aktuelle Themen, die<br />
in Gesellschaften der hoch entwickelten Länder<br />
diskutiert werden – explizit Klimawandel<br />
<strong>und</strong> erwartete Ressourcenknappheit. Die argumentative<br />
Weiterführung der relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
kommt hier zu kurz <strong>und</strong><br />
scheint in einem lock-in gefangen. Vielleicht<br />
liegt die größte Schwäche des Buches darin,<br />
sich immer <strong>und</strong> überall gegenüber der (neo-)<br />
klassischen deutschen Raumwirtschaftslehre<br />
abgrenzen zu müssen. Für den deutschen Leser<br />
ist es hier leicht zu folgen, denn die Autoren<br />
diskutieren oft auf der Gr<strong>und</strong>lage deutscher<br />
wirtschaftsgeographischer Literatur der vergangenen<br />
beiden Jahrzehnte. Dennoch erscheint<br />
diese Sicht dem Rezensenten als unterkomplex.<br />
Es ist eine dualistische Sicht auf die<br />
Fachwelt – ihr da draußen, wir da drinnen –,<br />
die eine vertiefende Auseinandersetzung mit<br />
der inzwischen vielfach vorliegenden Kritik<br />
am Konzept der relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
verhindert (z.B. durch Autoren wie Peter<br />
Sunley oder Henry Yeung; in deutscher<br />
Sprache z. B. VON FRIELING 2005). Davon gibt<br />
es genug, <strong>und</strong> sie bezieht sich vor allem auf<br />
eine als unzureichend empf<strong>und</strong>ene Durchdringung<br />
des Kontextes, in dem die Akteure „situativ“<br />
<strong>und</strong> „kontingent“ handeln; wobei der<br />
Kontext sowohl gesellschaftstheoretisch als<br />
auch sozialpsychologisch <strong>und</strong> kulturell gemeint<br />
sein kann – Letzteres etwa die noch in<br />
der Einleitung genannten „values, interpretive<br />
frameworks“ (vi) oder soziale Deutungsmuster<br />
bezeichnend.<br />
Die relationale <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> zeigt ihre<br />
Stärke gerade dann, wenn sie die Interaktivität<br />
der Handelnden selbst thematisiert. Angesichts<br />
der Vorliebe <strong>für</strong> qualitative Forschungsmethoden,<br />
die die Autoren anfangs äußern, ist<br />
es schon etwas paradox, dass die überzeugendsten<br />
empirischen Teile des Buches aus den<br />
quantitativen Netzwerkstudien im Beratungsmilieu<br />
bestehen (Kap. 6, 8, 10). Hier wird die<br />
Leistungsfähigkeit des Ansatzes – soziales<br />
Handeln über Vertrauen <strong>und</strong> Reputation <strong>und</strong><br />
„seiner“ Methode der quantitativen sozialen<br />
Netzwerkanalyse – genau <strong>und</strong> modern demonstriert.<br />
Auch die Beispiele fehlenden interaktiven<br />
Handelns, mangelnder Möglichkeiten<br />
<strong>für</strong> „buzz“ <strong>und</strong> „pipelines“, verweisen auf die<br />
Berechtigung der relationalen Perspektive<br />
(Kap. 7). Die Kap. 5 <strong>und</strong> 9 befassen sich dagegen<br />
mehr mit gegebenen Kontexten des Handelns;<br />
zum einen mit dem (hier nicht begründeten)<br />
Regierungshandeln beim Aufbau chinesischer<br />
Chemiekomplexe, zum anderen mit der<br />
Messe als ermöglichender Ort von sozialer Interaktion.<br />
Die „schwarze“ Seite der Vernetzung<br />
wird nicht einmal randlich angesprochen: Exklusion<br />
(von Wettbewerbern, Bevölkerungsgruppen),<br />
ungleiche Aneignung (von Einkommen)<br />
<strong>und</strong> Teilhabe (an Entscheidungen), blockierende<br />
Netze (lock-in) <strong>und</strong> ihre Wirkung<br />
auf Stagnation <strong>und</strong> Niedergang; letztlich also –<br />
entgegen der Forderung der Autoren – eine<br />
Diskussion um die situative Analyse der Nutzung<br />
von Macht.<br />
Folglich gilt es, noch viel konzeptionell nachzudenken<br />
<strong>und</strong> empirisch zu tun, wenn man die<br />
relationale <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> als ein aktuelles<br />
Projekt der scientific community verstehen<br />
will. Das Buch ist dazu eine – in sympathisierender<br />
Kritik – anregende Pflichtlektüre<br />
<strong>für</strong> alle Fachwissenschaftler. Der klare didaktische<br />
Aufbau der Teile <strong>und</strong> die Zusammenfassungen<br />
am Ende jeden Kapitels machen es<br />
auch <strong>für</strong> Masterkurse einsetzbar – wenn man<br />
um kritische Literatur ergänzt. Die sozialen<br />
Netzwerkanalysen mögen junge Wissenschaftler<br />
zu entsprechenden Arbeiten anregen. Die<br />
Autoren hegen schließlich berechtigt die Hoffnung,<br />
international weitere Aufmerksamkeit<br />
unter den Sozialwissenschaften zu gewinnen.<br />
Jedenfalls gibt das Buch als erste internationale<br />
Zusammenfassung des Konzepts der relationalen<br />
<strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> wichtige Anstöße<br />
zur wissenschaftlichen Debatte.
Literatur<br />
BATHELT, H./GLÜCKLER, J. (2002., 2003): <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>.<br />
Ökonomische Beziehungen in räumlicher<br />
Perspektive. Stuttgart. (2. korr. Aufl.)<br />
VON FRIELING, H.D. (2005): Die gesellschaftstheoretischen<br />
Gr<strong>und</strong>lagen der relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
– soziale Kosmologie <strong>und</strong> naturalistische Metaphern.<br />
In: Geographische Zeitschrift, (93)2, 82-99.<br />
Eike W. Schamp, Frankfurt am Main<br />
STEINECKE, ALBRECHT: Themenwelten im<br />
Tourismus. München: Oldenbourg Verlag<br />
2009, 362 S., € 39,80.<br />
Nach wie vor zählt der Tourismus zu den globalen<br />
Wachstumsbranchen. So geht die World<br />
Tourism Organization (WTO) der UN <strong>für</strong> das<br />
Jahr 2025 von weltweit 1,6 Mrd. Ankünften,<br />
inklusive der Geschäftsreisen (aber ohne den<br />
Binnentourismus mitzurechnen) im internationalen<br />
Reiseverkehr aus, was im Vergleich zu<br />
heute in etwa einer Verdoppelung gleichkäme.<br />
Lag 1971 der Anteil der fünf Top-Destinationen<br />
noch bei ca. 70 %, entfielen allerdings im<br />
Jahr 2008 nur mehr 31 % der grenzüberschreitenden<br />
Reisebewegungen auf die führenden<br />
fünf Staaten. Der Wettbewerb wächst <strong>und</strong> reife<br />
Destinationen verlieren zusehends an Boden.<br />
Als eine Reaktion darauf kann gerade <strong>für</strong><br />
Tourismusregionen, welche am Ende ihres<br />
Destinationslebenszyklus stehen, die Etablierung<br />
kommerzieller Themenwelten im Speziellen<br />
betrachtet werden. Auch allgemein ist<br />
die Thematisierung des Raumes durch Nutzung<br />
endogener Potenziale <strong>und</strong> in der Regel<br />
begleitet von darauf abgestellten Events (vgl.<br />
z.B. die ostschweizerische Ferienregion „Heidiland“,<br />
die die große Popularität der Heidi-<br />
Romane von Johanna Spyri zur Etablierung<br />
ihrer Dachmarke nutzt) ein Fakt, der damit in<br />
Zusammenhang steht. Freilich ist neben einer<br />
gerade in unseren Breiten unzweifelhaften<br />
Marktsättigung die generelle Emotionalisierung<br />
des Konsums <strong>und</strong> die Erlebnisorientierung<br />
der Freizeitgesellschaft ebenfalls mit verantwortlich<br />
da<strong>für</strong> zu machen. Denn Tourismus<br />
ist ein von der Nachfrage getriebenes Geschäft.<br />
Nun sind die teilweise als Kommerztempel<br />
scharf kritisierten künstlichen Themenwelten<br />
gar nicht so neu. Denn illusionär gestaltete Gebäudlichkeiten<br />
finden sich nicht nur, <strong>und</strong> dort<br />
besonders konzentriert, entlang des Strip im<br />
jungen Las Vegas. Seit mehr als 200 Jahren<br />
Buchbesprechungen<br />
115<br />
gehören sie zum architektonischen F<strong>und</strong>us der<br />
europäischen Kulturgeschichte. Beredtes Beispiel<br />
hier<strong>für</strong> ist etwa die im Münchner Schlosspark<br />
zu Nymphenburg anzutreffende Magdalenenklause,<br />
welche im Jahr 1725 als bewohnbare<br />
Ruine errichtet wurde. Trotzdem ist sowohl<br />
die Dimension <strong>und</strong> Marktstellung als auch die<br />
räumliche Verbreitung touristischer Themenwelten<br />
<strong>und</strong> den darin anzutreffenden Inszenierungstechniken<br />
heutzutage so prominent, dass<br />
es höchste Zeit <strong>für</strong> eine Monographie wie die<br />
vorliegende auch in deutscher Sprache <strong>und</strong> mit<br />
bevorzugt mitteleuropäischen Fallbeispielen<br />
bedurfte. Dabei bezieht der Autor durchaus die<br />
internationale Literatur zum Thema kenntnisreich<br />
mit ein.<br />
Der Verfasser folgt einer vornehmlich auf Fallstudien<br />
bezogenen Betrachtung <strong>und</strong> legt die jeweiligen<br />
spezifischen Charakteristiken ausgewählter<br />
Themenwelttypen zu folgenden Sachverhalten<br />
kompetent dar:<br />
– Freizeit- <strong>und</strong> Themenparks (wie z.B. das Disney<br />
Resort Paris oder der Europa-Park Rust<br />
als mit Abstand meistbesuchter Themenpark<br />
Deutschlands);<br />
– Themenhotels <strong>und</strong> -restaurants (wie z.B. die<br />
„Irish Pubs“ eines irischen Brauereikonzerns<br />
oder die „Hard Rock Cafés“);<br />
– Urban Entertainment Center (wie z.B. das<br />
Centro Oberhausen als größtes innerhalb<br />
Deutschlands);<br />
– Markenerlebniswelten oder „brand parks“<br />
(wie z.B. die Autowelt Wolfsburg oder das<br />
Legoland im bayerisch-schwäbischen Günzburg);<br />
– Zoologische Gärten/Aquarien (wie z.B. der<br />
Erlebniszoo Hannover).<br />
Dabei dekliniert der Autor die betreffenden<br />
Kapitel seines Werks jeweils mit einer einleitenden<br />
Definition, der historischen Entwicklung,<br />
den Merkmalen <strong>und</strong> international festzustellenden<br />
aktuellen Trends durch. Das Werk<br />
benennt nicht nur gelungene Vorhaben, sondern<br />
bezieht auch gescheiterte Projekte <strong>und</strong><br />
Gründe <strong>für</strong> deren Misserfolg mit ein (41). Hierbei<br />
ist eine wesentliche Vorbedingung <strong>für</strong> den<br />
Erfolg von Themenwelten eine hohe Bevölkerungsdichte<br />
im Umfeld (Erreichbarkeitsradius<br />
von 1,5 – 2 St<strong>und</strong>en Fahrzeit) <strong>und</strong> Nachfragepotenzial.<br />
Auch andere <strong>für</strong> Raumwissenschaftler<br />
zentrale Standortbedingungen werden angeführt<br />
(74, 151). Gut gefällt dem Rezensenten,<br />
dass nach jedem Abschnitt Zwischenfazits als
116 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Kastentexte die zentralen Botschaften zusammenfassen.<br />
Hierbei sind die vielschichtig präsentierten<br />
Inhalte nicht allein <strong>für</strong> Freizeit- <strong>und</strong><br />
Tourismusforscher lesenswert, sondern auch<br />
<strong>für</strong> Stadt- <strong>und</strong> teilweise auch Handelsgeographen<br />
interessant (252 ff.). Das Buch erscheint<br />
insofern in jeder Hinsicht lesenswert, auch<br />
wenn man die am Schluss stehende gewagte<br />
Hypothese des Verfassers „Mit dieser Entwicklung<br />
werden die Grenzen zwischen (angeblich)<br />
künstlichen Themenwelten <strong>und</strong> den (angeblich)<br />
authentischen Realwelten hinfällig.“<br />
(282) nicht unbedingt teilen muss.<br />
Hubert Job, Würzburg<br />
SCHERRER, CHRISTOPH (Ed.): China’s labor<br />
question. München: Rainer Hampp Verlag,<br />
2011, vii+221 pp., € 27,80. (e-book available:<br />
http://www.global-labour-university.org/<br />
fileadmin/books/CLQ_full_book.pdf).<br />
“China’s labor question” is a collection of papers<br />
based on presentations at a panel of alumni<br />
from a Master’s-level programme at a conference<br />
in Berlin in 2010 and has been replenished<br />
with additional invited contributions. Addressing<br />
a rapidly evolving issue of clear topical<br />
interest, the initiators of the volume have<br />
been keen to expedite publication, responding<br />
to “great interest among trade unionists and<br />
academics in learning more about workers’<br />
struggles in China” (vi). The initiative to publish<br />
junior researchers’ work speedily is laudable,<br />
for it is in my view an excellent element<br />
of training that allows budding researchers to<br />
gain valuable experience of publishing; for a<br />
group of young scholars, all non-native speakers<br />
of English, to cut their teeth on an English<br />
publication is the best possible preparation for<br />
the struggles of the academic world.<br />
Considering the importance of Chinese workers<br />
for the world economy, who manufacture a<br />
large proportion of the consumer goods for the<br />
European and North American markets, the<br />
reader approaches the book with considerable<br />
expectation. Systematic syntheses, fresh views<br />
and the application of new, critical approaches<br />
to dynamically changing data on economy,<br />
work and society are certainly needed, since<br />
the scholarly field has had a hard time catching<br />
up with developments. The book, although<br />
bold and refreshing in some respects, unfortunately<br />
does not meet these expectations. The<br />
kaleidoscopic character of the book is a defi-<br />
nite draw-back as it merely raises a large number<br />
of “challenges” without reaching a central<br />
idea of the processes of change in “labour relations.”<br />
I shall make this point with reference to<br />
two of the contributions.<br />
The book starts out with Hansjörg Herr’s<br />
analysis of high economic growth and its consequences<br />
for employment in China. The intention<br />
is excellent, but it starts out with eerily<br />
irrelevant approaches to economic growth, like<br />
the “neoclassical model” and “new growth theory,”<br />
which are rejected for a number of reasons,<br />
partly because the theories are flawed in<br />
themselves, partly because they are not measuring<br />
the phenomena presenting themselves in<br />
China other than in very abstract terms, and<br />
partly, I would add, because economic policy<br />
making in China defeated the presumptions of<br />
conventional economic theory. The attempt to<br />
explain growth with inequality, harking back to<br />
Simon Kuznets and his famous curve, is also rejected;<br />
interestingly, Hansjörg Herr <strong>und</strong>erstands<br />
that “Chinese leaders even seemed to<br />
follow the idea that increasing inequality is a<br />
good thing,” but he fails to follow up on this<br />
and concludes that the Kuznets curve “does not<br />
bear up,” mainly due to points of no relevance<br />
to the Chinese case. Instead he marries Joseph<br />
Schumpeter’s and Milton Keynes’ ideas in a<br />
“monetary development model” hoping to explain<br />
high economic growth rates in China.<br />
The model involves a cycle of credit-investment-income-savings<br />
and dictates that the productive<br />
(rather than speculative) nature of investments<br />
(as guided through the central bank)<br />
is crucial for economic growth. In the case of<br />
China, the risky reliance on international export<br />
processing incomes and the low domestic<br />
consumption rates have long been identified as<br />
potential obstacles to growth. The fact that<br />
high rates of social inequality stymy domestic<br />
consumption brings the author back to the conclusion<br />
that “the Chinese government has neglected<br />
the distribution question for too long.”<br />
The reader is left with very little <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
of China and a lot of chaff about debunked theories.<br />
And yet Herr does have a point that he<br />
could have pursued and measured: Exactly<br />
how the Chinese authorities systematically<br />
used the transition from one mode of planning<br />
to another and the manipulation of institutions<br />
like ownership (including the privatisation of<br />
state assets), household registration, land<br />
rights, enterprise reform and regulation and so<br />
on to achieve growth. That the policy since
2003 has been more focused on fairness does<br />
not indicate that the authorities are pursuing<br />
social equality, but rather that some of the inequalities<br />
arising from earlier policies have lost<br />
their usefulness and that the authorities promote<br />
other goals to consolidate economic<br />
growth, in that process not shying away from<br />
utilising other types of inequality. His bland<br />
conclusion that the Chinese success story can<br />
be ascribed to a “productive combination of<br />
government interaction and market forces”<br />
could have been the starting point and he could<br />
have used much more space on systematically<br />
discussing how the strong Chinese state managed<br />
to do what economics text books of any<br />
persuasion, even the works by Joseph Stiglitz,<br />
tell us is impossible. In stead of telling us that<br />
China’s “capitalist model is a specific and<br />
unique one,” he could have told us in what<br />
sense it is specific and what is so unique about<br />
it. Alas, he did not.<br />
Frido Wenten’s contribution on “restructured<br />
class relations” since 1978 seeks to use a historical-materialist<br />
approach to bring out an <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />
of social change. He homes in on<br />
the most important aspects that could provide<br />
answers, but fails to grasp them (and f<strong>und</strong>amentally<br />
mis<strong>und</strong>erstands crucial aspects). He<br />
points at the rural reforms, i.e. the introduction<br />
of the household responsibility system which<br />
between 1978 and 1983 transferred agricultural<br />
production back to rural households, he mentions<br />
the boost in rural incomes due to increase<br />
in state procurement prices and <strong>und</strong>erstands the<br />
rapid growth of the rural non-agricultural enterprise<br />
sector, as well as the huge rural-urban migration<br />
flows as “supply of cheap labour” to urban<br />
industry. He also <strong>und</strong>erstands the general<br />
issues of state-owned enterprise reform. However,<br />
he wrongly believes that the processes<br />
were “privatisation.” To the contrary, the state<br />
actively promoted the rural enterprise sector<br />
mainly as a collective sector, condoning new<br />
private enterprises as “red-cap companies,”<br />
changing the names of the “commune and<br />
brigade enterprises” into “township and village<br />
enterprises,” leading to township and town government<br />
control over the sector (the “local state<br />
coropratism,” as this has been termed by observers,<br />
dominated from the mid-1980s until<br />
sometime between 2005 and 2007, when townships<br />
and towns lost most of their economic<br />
functions). The efficiency gains the government<br />
sought to achieve in state owned enterprises<br />
had nothing to do with privatisation or capital-<br />
Buchbesprechungen<br />
117<br />
ism, and the “Democracy Wall Movement” had<br />
no working class agenda; Wei Jingsheng’s claim<br />
for a “fifth modernisation” was for “democracy”<br />
in an ideal and broad sense and certainly<br />
not for “democracy in enterprises”; the movement<br />
learnt from not only Lech Wałęsa’s Solidarność,<br />
but also studied texts by Rudolf Bahro,<br />
Milovan Djilas and many others in translations<br />
produced for exclusive use within the top ranks<br />
of the Chinese Communist Party – they did not<br />
seek worker solidarity against encroaching capitalism,<br />
but a critical <strong>und</strong>erstanding of power in<br />
socialist states. The idea that the late 1980s<br />
were characterised by worker activism (sparked<br />
by high inflation and also by the localised experiments<br />
with state-owned-enterprise reform<br />
in Liaoning), linking up students and workers,<br />
and ending in the “Tiananmen-massacre” compresses<br />
very diverse issues into an overly simplistic<br />
narrative of a working-class struggle that<br />
never took place. In the analysis of the state<br />
owned enterprise reform, Wenten fails to grasp<br />
the process of transition, seeing it more as a<br />
struggle than as a systemic change. Discussing<br />
the rural-urban labour migration as a major<br />
source of “primitive accumulation,” Wenten inadvertently<br />
strikes the central point, but sadly<br />
fails to make it the crux of what could have<br />
been an exciting analysis, thinking of it merely<br />
as the “subjective agency of migrant workers,”<br />
missing the point that their agency is bo<strong>und</strong>ed<br />
by the deliberate and careful calibration of administrative<br />
and other institutions by China’s<br />
central and local “developmental state” administrations<br />
within the parameters of their regulation<br />
of core market players. As for the Hu Jintao-era<br />
that began in 2003 and is nearing its end<br />
in 2012, Wenten believes that it mainly sought<br />
to address instability (partly due to worker activism<br />
and public protests) by backtracking and<br />
creating more social justice to make amends for<br />
the capitalist overdrive perpetrated by the Jiang<br />
Zemin leadership 1989-2002. Wenten does not<br />
systematically identify how proactive government<br />
policy making since the late 1990s and in<br />
particular during the Hu Jintao-era have gradually<br />
changed modes of capital accumulation,<br />
upgrading of technology and skills, location of<br />
industry, relations between agriculture and other<br />
sectors, and administrative and market structures<br />
of resource allocation and investment. By<br />
abandoning the basic political-economy principles<br />
of an historical-materialism approach and<br />
focusing on the affective aspects of worker activism,<br />
protest and social injustice, Wenten’s account<br />
does not reveal the direction of China’s
118 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
political-economy system, but only concludes<br />
that “social conflict” will continue into the future.<br />
I shall not discuss all the contributions in the<br />
book, although several are better focused and<br />
demonstrate a better empirical balance. In any<br />
case, what can be learned from this master<br />
class?<br />
– First, the authors should have let the manuscript<br />
be read by people with experience in<br />
the field of scholarship, willing to be genuinely<br />
critical, and they should have taken<br />
their advice and criticism seriously; the main<br />
lesson is that critique that allows one to<br />
change the manuscript before publication is<br />
something one learns from, while post-publication<br />
critique by reviewers only leads to<br />
grief.<br />
– Second, the authors should get to the core<br />
point and avoid empty theoretical deliberations.<br />
They should avoid using loose concepts<br />
or irrelevant theories.<br />
– Third, the authors should put away their personal<br />
sym- and antipathies, for nothing is<br />
more disturbing than misplaced solidarity<br />
and dissonant claims of unity, even if they<br />
are only hidden away in the subtext: Chinese<br />
working people can do without clammy embraces.<br />
– Fourth, the authors should avoid poaching<br />
other people’s interview quotes, taking them<br />
out of context. In particular Wenten sins<br />
against this principle.<br />
– Fifth, the authors should be meticulous when<br />
referring to other people’s work, avoiding to<br />
impute or infer meanings not expressed.<br />
Again, Wenten’s is prone to draw wrong conclusions<br />
from the works he refers to.<br />
– Sixth, the authors should be dispassionate,<br />
try to see the big picture and at the same time<br />
<strong>und</strong>erstand the actual dynamics at play. For<br />
example: Private ownership or the household<br />
registration system are not good or bad, they<br />
are facts the significance of which changes<br />
over time and varies across situations. Collective<br />
bargaining has no intrinsic merit, for<br />
its value is entirely determined by its context.<br />
Judging phenomena in China as everywhere<br />
else, one needs to see them in context, not<br />
isolated.<br />
– Seventh, the authors should get their work<br />
properly language edited in several iterations<br />
by people who are used to their field of<br />
scholarship. When English is the language of<br />
publication, the citation styles and all other<br />
detail must follow English conventions, even<br />
if the publisher is in Germany.<br />
The point I want to make is that a lot of enthusiasm<br />
and hard work has gone into this book,<br />
and that most of the f<strong>und</strong>amental flaws could<br />
have been avoided by more careful processes<br />
of pre-publication peer review, editing, and<br />
better scholarly practices. For example, some<br />
of the mistakes in Wenten’s work are not uncommon<br />
among young scholars, and better advising<br />
and mentoring should have smoothed<br />
them out. I fo<strong>und</strong> the book hard to read and<br />
hard to review, and I considered declining to<br />
review it at all. The fact that I do review it and<br />
choose to be emphatic and blunt about its flaws<br />
is that I hope that my comments at least can be<br />
of use, for I do believe that this type of publication<br />
is important, and that in the future we<br />
can make sure that young researchers are guided<br />
and supported by critical peer reviewers,<br />
their advisors, as well as commissioning editors,<br />
language editors and copy editors to better<br />
learn the skills of publishing internationally.<br />
We need new cohorts of highly skilled researchers,<br />
and the only way to achieve that is<br />
by providing both support and criticism. Even<br />
if the publication would be delayed by a year in<br />
order for it to become academically stronger<br />
and more credible, that year would be well<br />
spent.<br />
Flemming Christiansen, Duisburg-Essen<br />
ZIMMERMANN, GERD R.: Die Besiedlung Madagaskars<br />
durch „Indonesier“. Nackenheim/<br />
Rhein: Edition Matahari 2010, 6 Abb., 119 S.,<br />
€ 31,40.<br />
In seiner inzwischen schon klassischen Definition<br />
hat Anthony Giddens Globalisierung als<br />
Intensivierung weltweiter sozialer Beziehungen<br />
bezeichnet, durch die entfernte Orte so<br />
miteinander verb<strong>und</strong>en werden, dass Ereignisse<br />
an einem Ort durch Vorgänge geprägt werden,<br />
die sich an einem viele Kilometer entfernten<br />
Ort abspielen – <strong>und</strong> umgekehrt. Der aktuellen<br />
Globalisierung, die durch Prozesse räumlicher<br />
Verdichtung <strong>und</strong> zeitlicher Beschleunigung<br />
gekennzeichnet ist, kommt sicher gegenüber<br />
historisch weiter zurückliegenden Vorgängen<br />
eine neue Qualität zu. Aber Migrationen<br />
<strong>und</strong> Verflechtungen über große Distanzen hinweg<br />
finden sich auch bereits lange vor Beginn<br />
der europäischen Kolonialisierung der Welt.
Ein solches Beispiel ist zweifellos die Besiedlung<br />
Madagaskars durch Auswanderer aus der<br />
Inselwelt des heutigen Indonesien. Sie haben<br />
dabei seit Begin der Zeitrechnung, wahrscheinlich<br />
in mehreren Schüben, nicht nur Distanzen<br />
von über 6.000 km überw<strong>und</strong>en, sondern vermutlich<br />
auch bis zum 10. Jahrh<strong>und</strong>ert, vielleicht<br />
sogar bis zum 14. Jahrh<strong>und</strong>ert, Beziehungen zu<br />
ihren südostasiatischen Herkunftsräumen unterhalten.<br />
Auch wenn vieles mangels schriftlicher<br />
Quellen hypothetisch bleibt, etwa ob der Indische<br />
Ozean direkt überquert, oder ob küstennahe<br />
Routen gewählt wurden, es besteht kein<br />
Zweifel daran, dass die „Indonesier“ die Kultur<br />
Madagaskars nachhaltig geprägt haben. Der<br />
Autor demonstriert in seiner verdienstvollen<br />
Studie eindrucksvoll, wie ein explizit geographischer<br />
Zugang die bisher dominierende linguistische<br />
<strong>und</strong> ethnologische Forschung zum<br />
Thema erkenntnisfördernd, gerade auch im<br />
Sinn der Generierung fruchtbarer Forschungshypothesen,<br />
bereichern kann. Dies betrifft unter<br />
anderem Fragen nach den Herkunftsräumen der<br />
Migranten im heutigen Indonesien, in Madagaskar<br />
nach den Beziehungen zwischen verschiedenen<br />
Einwanderergruppen <strong>und</strong> zwischen<br />
Küste <strong>und</strong> Hochland sowie nach der Ausbreitung<br />
von Kulturelementen wie etwa dem Nassreisanbau.<br />
Die Studie zeigt exemplarisch, dass<br />
es bereits lange vor der europäischen „Entdeckung“<br />
der Welt Verflechtungen über große<br />
Distanzen <strong>und</strong> über lange Zeiträume gegeben<br />
hat, die zu bis heute nachwirkenden, sozial <strong>und</strong><br />
auch politisch bedeutsamen kulturellen Hybridisierungen<br />
geführt haben. Es ist zu wünschen,<br />
dass die beigefügten Übersetzungen der Zusammenfassung<br />
ins Englische, Französische,<br />
Indonesische <strong>und</strong> Madagassische der internationalen<br />
Rezeption der ausgesprochen lesenswerten<br />
Studie förderlich sind.<br />
Helmut Schneider, Duisburg-Essen<br />
JOB, HUBERT/ WOLTERING, MANUEL/ HAR-<br />
RER, BERNHARD: Regionalökonomische Effekte<br />
des Tourismus in deutschen Nationalparken.<br />
Bonn-Bad Godesberg: B<strong>und</strong>esamt <strong>für</strong><br />
Naturschutz 2009, 186 S. € 18,-. (Naturschutz<br />
<strong>und</strong> Biologische Vielfalt, Band 76).<br />
Die Diskussion um die erwarteten <strong>und</strong> tatsächlichen<br />
Beiträge von Großschutzgebieten, namentlich<br />
Nationalparken, zur Regionalentwicklung<br />
ist keineswegs neu. Im Gegenteil wird<br />
darüber seit längerem kontrovers debattiert,<br />
Buchbesprechungen<br />
119<br />
um so mehr als mit dem gegenwärtigen paradigmatischen<br />
Wandel des Gebietsschutzes das<br />
Verhältnis von Naturschutz <strong>und</strong> Regionalentwicklung<br />
immer stärker in den Fokus rückt. Im<br />
Zentrum steht dabei die Vorstellung, großräumige<br />
Schutzgebiete könnten im Sinne eines integrative<br />
Ansatzes insbesondere in Mitteleuropa<br />
wertvolle Beiträge zur Regionalentwicklung<br />
beisteuern. Dem Tourismus galt <strong>und</strong> gilt dabei<br />
besondere Aufmerksamkeit, vor allem weil<br />
Nationalparke bereits per Gesetz auch als Vorranggebiete<br />
<strong>für</strong> die Erholung fungieren. Die<br />
diesbezüglichen Erwartungen sind gemeinhin<br />
hoch, ohne dass allerdings lange Zeit hinlänglich<br />
gesichert schien, welche ökonomischen<br />
Wirkungen vom Tourismus, insbesondere in<br />
monetärer Hinsicht tatsächlich auszugehen<br />
vermögen.<br />
Schon 2009 hat eine Arbeitsgruppe um Hubert<br />
Job von der Universität Würzburg eine Studie<br />
zu den regionalökonomischen Effekten des<br />
Tourismus in deutschen Nationalparken vorgelegt,<br />
die inzwischen vielfach zitiert wird. Aus<br />
guten Gründen soll an dieser Stelle ein weiteres<br />
Mal eine Empfehlung zur Lektüre des Bandes<br />
ausgesprochen werden, dessen Rezeption<br />
eine Versachlichung verspricht, vor allem aber<br />
eine große Zahl belastbarer Daten zur weiteren<br />
Diskussion um den Nationalparktourismus in<br />
Deutschland bereitstellt.<br />
Auf der Basis einer touristischen Wertschöpfungsanalyse,<br />
der aufgr<strong>und</strong> ihrer offenk<strong>und</strong>igen<br />
Vorteile der Vorrang gegenüber anderen,<br />
konkurrierenden Konzepten der Wirkungsforschung<br />
im Tourismus gegeben wurde, präsentieren<br />
Job <strong>und</strong> seine Kollegen eine Fallstudienuntersuchung<br />
sechs ausgewählter „typischer“<br />
Nationalparke in Deutschland. Im Zuge diverser<br />
empirischer Erhebungen in den jeweiligen<br />
Schutzgebieten, die methodisch konsistent,<br />
aber gleichermaßen aufwendig <strong>und</strong> mühevoll<br />
erscheinen, konnten Daten gewonnen werden,<br />
deren Interpretation nunmehr <strong>für</strong> die ausgewählten<br />
Parke, namentlich Bayerischer Wald,<br />
Eifel, Hainich, Kellerwald-Edersee <strong>und</strong> Niedersächsisches<br />
Wattenmeer, sowie als Schätzung<br />
auch <strong>für</strong> alle deutschen Nationalparke<br />
Aussagen zum Umfang der regionalökonomischen<br />
Wertschöpfung des Tourismus erlauben.<br />
Die Konzeption der vom B<strong>und</strong>esamt <strong>für</strong> den<br />
Naturschutz in Auftrag gegebenen Studie ist<br />
dabei nicht ganz neu, da Job <strong>und</strong> andere bereits<br />
2005 <strong>und</strong> zuvor 2003 ähnliche Pilotstudien<br />
durchgeführt hatten. Ursprünglich geht das
120 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />
Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />
Untersuchungskonzept auf die Schweizerin<br />
Irene Küpfer zurück, die schon 2000 eine entsprechende<br />
Studie zum Schweizerischen<br />
Nationalpark vorlegen konnte. Die Novität der<br />
Gesamtschau aller Nationalparke als „Flaggschiffe“<br />
des Gebietsschutzes in Deutschland ist<br />
deswegen gleichwohl kaum zu übersehen!<br />
Die Ergebnisse geben den vielfachen Vermutungen<br />
Recht, dass der Nationalparktourismus<br />
sehr wohl beträchtliche Beiträge zur ökonomischen<br />
Wertschöpfung auf regionaler Ebene beizusteuern<br />
vermag, die gleichermaßen Einkommens-<br />
<strong>und</strong> Beschäftigungseffekte umfassen.<br />
Diese variieren, wenig überraschend, von Nationalpark<br />
zu Nationalpark, wobei <strong>für</strong> den vergleichsweise<br />
jungen Nationalpark Eifel die<br />
größten Wirkungen konstatiert werden. Entscheidend<br />
ist hierbei die Definition der Nationalparkbesucher<br />
im engeren Sinne, also der<br />
Gäste, die das Schutzgebiet ausdrücklich wegen<br />
des Prädikats Nationalpark besuchen. In einem<br />
Schutzgebiet wie dem Nationalpark Niedersächsisches<br />
Wattenmeer, das lange vor seiner<br />
Erklärung zum Nationalpark eine klassische<br />
Urlaubsdestination war, müssen diese Wirkungen<br />
notwendigerweise geringer ausfallen.<br />
Die Präsidentin des B<strong>und</strong>esamtes <strong>für</strong> Naturschutz,<br />
Beate Jessel, hat in ihrem Vorwort die<br />
Bedeutung der vorliegenden Studie <strong>für</strong> die<br />
weitere Debatte um die Bedeutung von Nationalparken<br />
in ihrer Funktion als Tourismusdestinationen<br />
<strong>für</strong> die regionale Wirtschaft vorrangig<br />
peripherer ländlicher Räume herausgestellt.<br />
Dass zudem mit der Studie auch detailliertere<br />
Kenntnisse zur Besucherstruktur <strong>und</strong><br />
Motivation von Gästen gewonnen werden<br />
konnten, ist ein beachtlicher „Nebeneffekt“ der<br />
Untersuchung, der vor allem <strong>für</strong> die weiteren<br />
Bemühungen im Rahmen eines professionellen<br />
Destinationsmanagements <strong>für</strong> die Nationalparke,<br />
aber auch andere Großschutzgebiete von<br />
erheblichem Wert sein dürfte. Die Gründung<br />
der Dachmarke „Nationale Naturlandschaften“<br />
kann beispielhaft <strong>für</strong> die Richtung stehen, in<br />
welche sich das Marketing der Großschutzgebiete<br />
bei der Herausstellung ihrer unverwechselbaren<br />
Alleinstellungsmerkmale in Zukunft<br />
weiter entwickeln sollten.<br />
Indes sei abschließend vor möglicher Euphorie<br />
angesichts der vorgelegten Ergebnisse gewarnt.<br />
Mögen diese gerade <strong>für</strong> periphere ländliche<br />
Räume auch vielversprechend erscheinen,<br />
so sollte doch keineswegs von einem Au-<br />
tomatismus regionalökonomischer Wirkungen<br />
des Tourismus ausgegangen werden. Wie unter<br />
anderen Luisa Vogt (2008) eindrucksvoll nachweisen<br />
konnte, sind dem Tourismus als vermeintlichem<br />
Motor der Regionalentwicklung<br />
in der ländlichen Peripherie häufig enge Grenzen<br />
gesetzt. Von entscheidender Bedeutung<br />
sind vor allem das zur Verfügung stehende<br />
Humankapital, Kooperationsbereitschaft, aber<br />
auch infrastrukturelle Voraussetzungen sowie<br />
ein professionelles Destinationsmanagement,<br />
um auch in der Peripherie entsprechende Entwicklungseffekte<br />
erzielen zu können. Nationalparke<br />
bieten in dieser Hinsicht sicherlich Vorteile<br />
gegenüber anderen Konstellationen, inwieweit<br />
die Ergebnisse der vorliegenden Studie<br />
allerdings verallgemeinerbar sind, insbesondere<br />
im europäischen Kontext, bedarf<br />
zweifellos noch der weiteren Forschung. In<br />
diesem Sinne wäre ein Blick auf vergleichbare<br />
Studien in anderen Ländern <strong>und</strong> deren Ergebnisse<br />
wünschenswert gewesen; hierauf gehen<br />
Job <strong>und</strong> Kollegen allerdings nicht weiter ein.<br />
Ohnehin sollten im Blick auf die ökonomischen<br />
Effekte des Tourismus, die zweifellos im Fokus<br />
der hier rezensierten Untersuchung standen, die<br />
weiteren Anliegen des Naturschutzes nicht aus<br />
dem Blick geraten. Dies ist auch <strong>und</strong> gerade aus<br />
der Perspektive eines integrativen Gebietsschutzes<br />
essentiell. Erholung <strong>und</strong> Freizeit in der Natur,<br />
Förderung der Ges<strong>und</strong>heit, persönliche Erbauung<br />
<strong>und</strong> Weckung von Kreativität, sowie die<br />
Beiträge zur Umweltbildung sind wesentliche<br />
gesellschaftliche Leistungen von Nationalparken,<br />
deren Stellenwert es <strong>für</strong> die Zukunft zu<br />
wahren <strong>und</strong> zu stärken gilt. Hiermit ist letztlich<br />
eine ideelle Gr<strong>und</strong>satzfrage angesprochen. So<br />
bedarf es angesichts der konkurrierenden Interessen,<br />
denen sich Schutzgebiete nach wie vor<br />
ausgesetzt sehen, so hat Reinhard Piechockie<br />
kürzlich in seinem ebenso lesenswerten Buch<br />
zur Ideengeschichte des Naturschutzes „Landschaft<br />
– Heimat – Wildnis“ unterstrichen, einer<br />
Doppelstrategie des Naturschutzes: Dieser muss<br />
wertvolle Naturlandschaften weiterhin bewahren<br />
<strong>und</strong> zugleich dem Menschen als Erfahrungsräume<br />
mit touristischer Qualität öffnen. Nur so<br />
wird auch die Akzeptanz <strong>für</strong> mehr <strong>und</strong> bessere<br />
Schutzgebiete, namentlich Nationalparke weiter<br />
wachsen können. Genau hierin könnte der eigentliche<br />
Gewinn liegen, der mit den regionalökonomischen<br />
Effekten von Nationalparken,<br />
nicht nur in Deutschland, zu erzielen ist.<br />
Ingo Mose, Oldenburg