14.12.2012 Views

International Review of Waste Management Policy - Department of ...

International Review of Waste Management Policy - Department of ...

International Review of Waste Management Policy - Department of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>:<br />

Annexes to Main Report<br />

Authors:<br />

Eunomia (UK), Tobin Consulting Engineers (Ireland),<br />

Öko-Institute (Germany), Arcadis (Belgium), Scuola<br />

Agraria del Parco di Monza (Italy), TBU Engineering<br />

(Austria), Eunomia New Zealand (New Zealand)<br />

29 th September 2009


Report for:<br />

Mr. Michael Layde, <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government, Ireland<br />

Prepared by:<br />

Dr Dominic Hogg, Dr Adrian Gibbs, Ann Ballinger, Andrew Coulthurst, Tim Elliott, Dr Debbie<br />

Fletcher, Simon Russell, Chris Sherrington, Sam Taylor (Eunomia), Duncan Wilson (Eunomia<br />

New Zealand), Sean Finlay, Damien Grehan, Mairead Hogan, Pat O’Neill (Tobin), Martin<br />

Steiner (TBU), Andreas Hermann, Matthias Buchert (Oko Institut), Ilse Laureysens, Mike van<br />

Acoyleyn (Arcadis), Enzo Favoino and Valentina Caimi (Scuola Agraria del Parco di Monza)<br />

Approved by:<br />

………………………………………………….<br />

Joe Papineschi<br />

(Director)<br />

Contact Details<br />

Eunomia Research & Consulting Ltd<br />

62 Queen Square<br />

Bristol<br />

BS1 4JZ<br />

United Kingdom<br />

Tel: +44 (0)117 9450100<br />

Fax: +44 (0)8717 142942<br />

Web: www.eunomia.co.uk<br />

Acknowledgements<br />

We are grateful to the Steering Group for this project and to those who contributed to the<br />

Consultative Group meetings. Several organisations also made submissions in writing and we<br />

are very grateful to them for the time spent doing so, and the insights provided.<br />

Disclaimer<br />

Eunomia Research & Consulting has taken due care in the preparation <strong>of</strong> this document to<br />

ensure that all facts and analysis presented are as accurate as possible within the scope <strong>of</strong><br />

the project. However Eunomia makes no warranty, express or implied, with respect to the use<br />

<strong>of</strong> any information disclosed in this document, or assumes any liabilities with respect to the<br />

use <strong>of</strong>, or damage resulting in any way from the use <strong>of</strong> any information disclosed in this<br />

document.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


29/09/09


Contents<br />

WASTE WASTE POLICIES POLICIES POLICIES – EXISTING EXISTING FRAMEWORK FRAMEWORK AND AND SOME SOME THEORETICAL THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS<br />

CONSIDERATIONS.......<br />

CONSIDERATIONS ....... 1<br />

i<br />

1.0 <strong>Waste</strong> Policies – a <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Existing Framework .....................................................2<br />

2.0 <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>....................................................................31<br />

KEY KEY KEY INSTITUTIONAL INSTITUTIONAL INSTITUTIONAL ISSUES ISSUES................................<br />

ISSUES ISSUES................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

......................................<br />

................................ ...... ......42 ...... 42 42<br />

3.0 Competition in the Market for <strong>Waste</strong> Collection.............................................................44<br />

4.0 The Role <strong>of</strong> Local Authorities............................................................................................63<br />

5.0 Governance Structures / Responsibilities for Delivery <strong>of</strong> National Strategy ................74<br />

POLICIES POLICIES POLICIES FOR FOR FOR MUNICIPAL MUNICIPAL MUNICIPAL WASTE WASTE................................<br />

WASTE WASTE................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

.............................................................<br />

................................ .............................<br />

.............................84<br />

............................. 84 84<br />

6.0 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Irish <strong>Policy</strong> on Prevention and Recycling........................................................85<br />

7.0 Pay-By-Use - Ireland ....................................................................................................... 103<br />

8.0 Pay-by-use - <strong>International</strong> .............................................................................................. 118<br />

9.0 Pay-by-use – Germany ................................................................................................... 159<br />

10.0 Pay-by-use – Flanders, Belgium................................................................................. 176<br />

11.0 Landfill Levy - Ireland.................................................................................................. 185<br />

12.0 Producer Responsibility, Packaging - Ireland............................................................ 199<br />

13.0 Producer Responsibility, Packaging - <strong>International</strong>.................................................. 229<br />

14.0 Producer Responsibility, Packaging - Germany ........................................................ 253<br />

15.0 Producer Responsibility – Flanders, Belgium........................................................... 263<br />

16.0 Deposit Refund Systems - <strong>International</strong> ................................................................... 297<br />

17.0 Deposit Refund Scheme - Germany .......................................................................... 340<br />

18.0 National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme - Ireland ..................................................... 350<br />

19.0 Producer Responsibility, WEEE - Ireland................................................................... 362<br />

20.0 Producer Responsibility, WEEE - <strong>International</strong> ......................................................... 376<br />

21.0 Producer Responsibility, WEEE - Germany................................................................ 406<br />

22.0 Producer Responsibility, ELVs - Ireland..................................................................... 417<br />

23.0 Producer Responsibility, ELVs - <strong>International</strong>........................................................... 431<br />

24.0 Producer Responsibility, Batteries - Ireland.............................................................. 448<br />

25.0 Producer Responsibility, Batteries - <strong>International</strong>.................................................... 457<br />

26.0 Producer Responsibility, Batteries - Germany .......................................................... 478<br />

27.0 Plastic Bag Levy - Ireland ........................................................................................... 487<br />

28.0 Packaging Taxes - <strong>International</strong>................................................................................. 498<br />

29.0 Tyre Charge - <strong>International</strong>......................................................................................... 508<br />

30.0 Product Taxes - Belgium............................................................................................. 515<br />

31.0 Plastic Bag Bans – <strong>International</strong> ............................................................................... 525<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


ii<br />

32.0 Levy on <strong>Waste</strong> Paints - <strong>International</strong>......................................................................... 529<br />

33.0 Circular WPPR 17/08 - Ireland .................................................................................. 533<br />

34.0 Minimum Recycling Standards (Household <strong>Waste</strong>) - <strong>International</strong>......................... 543<br />

35.0 Minimum Recycling Standards (Commercial and Industrial <strong>Waste</strong>) - <strong>International</strong><br />

564<br />

36.0 Product Standards: Biowaste Treatment Products - <strong>International</strong>.......................... 570<br />

37.0 Animal By–Products Regulations – Ireland .............................................................. 588<br />

38.0 Policies For Dealing With Junk Mail........................................................................... 598<br />

CONSTRUCTION CONSTRUCTION CONSTRUCTION AND AND AND DEMOLITION DEMOLITION DEMOLITION WASTE WASTE................................<br />

WASTE WASTE................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

.............................................<br />

................................ ............. .............604<br />

............. 604 604<br />

39.0 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Irish <strong>Policy</strong>, Construction & Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> ........................................ 605<br />

40.0 National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council - Ireland .............................. 608<br />

41.0 Landfill Levy - Ireland.................................................................................................. 616<br />

42.0 C & D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan Guidelines - Ireland............................................... 626<br />

43.0 Site <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans - <strong>International</strong> ......................................................... 632<br />

44.0 <strong>Waste</strong> Facility Permit Regulations - Ireland .............................................................. 644<br />

45.0 Demolition Protocol - UK ............................................................................................ 650<br />

46.0 Tax on Aggregates - <strong>International</strong> .............................................................................. 653<br />

47.0 Product Standards for Aggregates - <strong>International</strong> .................................................... 667<br />

48.0 Minimum Recycling Standards (Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>) - <strong>International</strong><br />

673<br />

49.0 Incentives Affecting Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> - Belgium ....................... 690<br />

50.0 Minimum Recycling Standards (Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>) - Germany. 691<br />

POLICIES POLICIES FOR FOR RESIDUAL RESIDUAL WASTE WASTE ................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................<br />

................................<br />

............................................................<br />

................................ ............................<br />

............................693<br />

............................ 693<br />

51.0 The Landfill Directive – Current Situation................................................................. 694<br />

52.0 Policies Aimed at Discouraging Disposal .................................................................. 727<br />

53.0 Landfill Ban (German Case Study)............................................................................. 794<br />

54.0 <strong>Waste</strong> Levies and Bans (Belgium-Flanders Case Study) ......................................... 800<br />

55.0 Landfill Allowance Schemes (UK) .............................................................................. 808<br />

56.0 Proposed <strong>Policy</strong> Changes ........................................................................................... 824<br />

OTHER OTHER POLICIES POLICIES................................<br />

POLICIES POLICIES................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

......................................................<br />

................................ ......................<br />

......................845<br />

...................... 845 845<br />

57.0 Green Public Procurement ......................................................................................... 846<br />

58.0 Ireland and the UNECE / Stockholm Conventions ................................................... 862<br />

TARGET TARGET SETTING SETTING................................<br />

SETTING SETTING................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

.....................................................<br />

................................ .....................<br />

.....................867<br />

..................... 867<br />

59.0 Target Setting.............................................................................................................. 868<br />

GRANT GRANT GRANT FUNDING FUNDING................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

.....................................................<br />

................................ .....................<br />

.....................901<br />

..................... 901<br />

60.0 Grant Funding ............................................................................................................. 902<br />

29/09/09


TECHNICAL TECHNICAL ANNEXES ANNEXES................................<br />

ANNEXES ANNEXES................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

................................................................<br />

................................ ................................<br />

.............................................<br />

................................ ............. ............. 930 930<br />

930<br />

iii<br />

61.0 Appraisal <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment Options...................................................... 931<br />

62.0 Life-cycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment Technologies ....................... 964<br />

63.0 Externalities <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options ........................................................... 978<br />

64.0 Costs <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong> Collection .....................................................................1033<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Glossary <strong>of</strong> Acronyms<br />

iv<br />

29/09/09<br />

ABP Belgian Pharmaceutical Association<br />

ADF Advanced disposal fee<br />

AOO Netherlands <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Council<br />

ARF Advance recycling fees<br />

AVGI Belgian Pharmaceutical Industry Association<br />

B2C Business to consumer<br />

B2B Business to business<br />

BAT Best available techniques<br />

BDMV Belgian Direct Marketing Association<br />

BEBAT Belgian producer responsibility organisation for batteries<br />

BMW Biodegradable municipal waste<br />

BPF Belgian Petrol Federation<br />

BVDU Belgian Association <strong>of</strong> Publishers<br />

C&D Construction and demolition (wastes)<br />

C&I Commercial and industrial (wastes)<br />

CA sites/CAS Civic Amenity Sites<br />

CARE Carpet America Recovery Effort<br />

CCMA City and County Managers Association<br />

CEN European Committee for Standardisation<br />

CIF Construction Industry Federation<br />

CLRTAP Convention on Long-range Transboundary Air Pollution<br />

COP4 Fourth Conference <strong>of</strong> the Parties<br />

CPI Consumer Price Index<br />

CPT Core Prevention Team<br />

Cre Composting Association Ireland<br />

CRT Cathode ray tube<br />

DAFF <strong>Department</strong> for Agriculture, Fisheries and Forestry<br />

DIFTAR Differentiated tariffs (pay-by-use)<br />

DfE Design for the Environment<br />

DGRNE-OWD Wallonian Directorate General for Natural Resources and<br />

Environment - Wallonian Office for <strong>Waste</strong><br />

DoEHLG <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage and Local Government<br />

DPG Deutsche Pfandsystem GmbH


v<br />

DSD Duales System Deutschland<br />

DVC Differential and variable charging (pay-by-use)<br />

DVR Differential and variable rate charging (pay-by-use)<br />

EEA European Environment Agency<br />

EfW Energy from waste<br />

ELVs End <strong>of</strong> life vehicles<br />

EMAS Eco-management and Audit Scheme<br />

EPA Environmental Protection Agency<br />

EPR Extended producer responsibility<br />

ESRI Economic and Social Research Institute<br />

EWC European <strong>Waste</strong> Catalogue<br />

FEBELAUTO Belgian confederation gathering the different groupings <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Belgian automotive sector<br />

FEBELGEN Generic pharmaceutical organisation<br />

FEBELGRA Federation <strong>of</strong> the Belgian printing and communication industry<br />

FEDIS Belgian federation <strong>of</strong> distributors<br />

GDP Gross Domestic Product<br />

GHG Greenhouse Gas<br />

HCB Hexachlorobenzene<br />

Hhld Household<br />

IBEC The Irish Business and Employers Confederation<br />

ISO 14001 Environmental management systems<br />

IWMA Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Association<br />

JCPRA Japan Containers and Packaging Recycling Association<br />

JRC Joint Research Centre (European Commission)<br />

LA Local authority<br />

LAB Association Belgium<br />

LCA Life cycle assessment<br />

MBO Milieubeleidsovereenkomst-environmental policy agreements<br />

with producers<br />

MBT Mechanical biological treatment<br />

MDG Market Development Group<br />

MPC Marginal private costs<br />

MRF Materials recovery facility<br />

MS (EU) Member State<br />

MSC Marginal social costs<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


vi<br />

29/09/09<br />

MSW Municipal solid waste<br />

NAVETEX National Association <strong>of</strong> Textile Retailers<br />

NBWS National biodegradable waste strategy<br />

NGO Non-governmental organization<br />

NFIW National Association <strong>of</strong> Informative Magazines<br />

NIR Near infrared<br />

NVGV National Organisation <strong>of</strong> Pharmaceutical Wholesalers<br />

Octa BDE’ Octa-brominated diphenyl ether<br />

OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development<br />

OEE Office <strong>of</strong> Environmental Enforcement<br />

OFBMW Organic fraction <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste<br />

OPHACO Belgian Association <strong>of</strong> Pharmaceutical Cooperatives<br />

OVAM The Public Flemish <strong>Waste</strong> Agency<br />

PAHs Polycyclic aromatic hydrocarbons<br />

PAYT Pay-as-you-throw (pay-by-use)<br />

PBU Pay-by-use<br />

PBUC Pay by use charge<br />

PCBs Polychlorinated biphenyls<br />

Penta BDE’ Penta brominated diphenyl ether<br />

PERN Packaging export recovery note<br />

PET Polyethylene terephthalate<br />

PMD Plastiek, Metaal en Drankverpakkingen (packaging made <strong>of</strong><br />

plastic, metal and drinks cartons)<br />

PPP Public private partnership<br />

POPs Persistent organic pollutants<br />

PRN Packaging recovery note<br />

PRO Producer responsibility organisation<br />

R&D Research and development<br />

RBRC Rechargeable Battery Recycling Corporation<br />

RECUPEL Flemish producer responsibility organisation dealing with waste<br />

electrical and electronic equipment<br />

RECYBAT Flemish producer responsibility organisation dealing with<br />

accumulators.<br />

RIA Regulatory impact assessment<br />

RPS Repak payment system<br />

RWMPs Regional waste management plans


vii<br />

SNIFFER Scotland and Northern Ireland Forum for Environmental Research<br />

UUPP <strong>International</strong> Federation <strong>of</strong> Periodical Press<br />

UN-ECE United Nations Economic Commission for Europe<br />

WEEE <strong>Waste</strong> electrical and electronic equipment<br />

WFD <strong>Waste</strong> framework directive<br />

WFL <strong>Waste</strong> facility levy<br />

WID <strong>Waste</strong> incineration directive<br />

WRAP <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action Programme (UK)<br />

VALORLUB Belgian producer responsibility organisation dealing with waste<br />

oils<br />

VDV Association <strong>of</strong> food retailers<br />

VEGRAB Federation <strong>of</strong> printing companies<br />

VLACO The Flemish organisation for promoting composting and compost<br />

use<br />

VLAREA Flemish regulation for waste<br />

VFG Vegetable, fruit and garden (biowaste)<br />

VROM The Netherlands Ministry <strong>of</strong> Housing, Spatial Planning and the<br />

Environment<br />

VUKPP Federation <strong>of</strong> Catholic Periodical Press<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


WASTE POLICIES – EXISTING FRAMEWORK AND<br />

SOME THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS<br />

1<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


1.0 <strong>Waste</strong> Policies – a <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Existing<br />

Framework<br />

Irish waste management has made enormous strides over the past decade. The<br />

statistics tell a story <strong>of</strong> impressive improvements in performance in many areas,<br />

whilst some <strong>of</strong> the improvements are not so readily revealed though appeal to<br />

statistics alone (for example, with regard to the effects <strong>of</strong> closing down old ‘dumps’<br />

which posed a threat to the environment).<br />

The changes which Ireland has made have been, to a considerable degree, motivated<br />

by policies emanating from Europe. Much focus tends to fall upon the so-called<br />

Producer Responsibility Directives in this regard, yet the impact <strong>of</strong> changes to the<br />

operation and regulation <strong>of</strong> landfills has also been significant. This has increased the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> disposal, and thereby increased the benefits associated with avoiding<br />

disposal (through prevention, re-use, recycling and alternative treatments). Recycling,<br />

in particular, is likely to have been incentivised by the escalation in landfill gate fees.<br />

In this Annex, we outline what we believe to be the salient issues in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

European waste policy and legislation as it affects Ireland. It would not be possible to<br />

look at each and every aspect <strong>of</strong> each piece <strong>of</strong> policy. The overview is unashamedly<br />

forward-looking. It looks to the future with a view to understanding the challenges<br />

ahead, rather than seeking to dwell on past achievements.<br />

1.1 The Priority Status <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

As is well known, waste prevention lies at the top <strong>of</strong> the waste management<br />

hierarchy. The status <strong>of</strong> waste prevention in this respect has been reinforced by the<br />

revised <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive (WFD) under Article 4: 1<br />

2<br />

29/09/09<br />

“1. The following waste hierarchy shall apply as a priority order in waste<br />

prevention and management legislation and policy:<br />

a) prevention;<br />

b) preparing for re-use;<br />

c) recycling;<br />

d) other recovery, e.g. energy recovery; and<br />

e) disposal.<br />

2. When applying the waste hierarchy referred to in paragraph 1, Member<br />

States shall take measures to encourage the options that deliver the best<br />

overall environmental outcome. This may require specific waste streams<br />

1 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and the Council <strong>of</strong> 19 November 2008 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Repealing Certain Directives.


3<br />

departing from the hierarchy where this is justified by life-cycle thinking on the<br />

overall impacts <strong>of</strong> the generation and management <strong>of</strong> such waste.<br />

Member States shall ensure that the development <strong>of</strong> waste legislation and<br />

policy is a fully transparent process, observing existing national rules about<br />

the consultation and involvement <strong>of</strong> citizens and stakeholders.<br />

Member States shall take into account the general environmental protection<br />

principles <strong>of</strong> precaution and sustainability, technical feasibility and economic<br />

viability, protection <strong>of</strong> resources as well as the overall environmental, human<br />

health, economic and social impacts, in accordance with Articles 1 and 13.”<br />

The above suggests that other than where life-cycle thinking suggests otherwise,<br />

prevention and preparing for re-use should be considered priority areas for waste<br />

management policy in future. Indeed, the WFD sets out a requirement for Member<br />

States to develop <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programmes under Articles 29 to 31: 2<br />

“Article Article 29<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> prevention programmes<br />

1. Member States shall establish, in accordance with Articles 1 and 4, 4, 4, waste<br />

prevention programmes not later than [five years and 20 days after<br />

publication <strong>of</strong> the WFD in the Official Journal].<br />

Such programmes shall be integrated either into the waste management<br />

plans provided for in Article 28 or into other environmental policy<br />

programmes, as appropriate, or shall function as separate programmes. If any<br />

such programme is integrated into the waste management plan or into other<br />

programmes, the waste prevention measures shall be clearly identified.<br />

2. The programmes provided for in paragraph 1 shall set out the waste<br />

prevention objectives Member States shall describe the existing prevention<br />

measures and evaluate the usefulness <strong>of</strong> the examples <strong>of</strong> measures indicated<br />

in Annex IV or other appropriate measures.<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> such objectives and measures shall be to break the link between<br />

economic growth and the environmental impacts associated with the<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

3. Member States shall determine appropriate specific qualitative or<br />

quantitative benchmarks for waste prevention measures adopted in order to<br />

monitor and assess the progress <strong>of</strong> the measures and may determine specific<br />

qualitative or quantitative targets and indicators, other than those referred to<br />

in paragraph 4, for the same purpose.<br />

4. Indicators for waste prevention measures may be adopted in accordance<br />

with the procedure referred to in Article 39 (3).<br />

2 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and the Council <strong>of</strong> 19 November 2008 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Repealing Certain Directives.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


4<br />

29/09/09<br />

5. The Commission shall create create create a a a system system system for for for sharing sharing sharing information information on on best best<br />

practice practice regarding regarding waste waste pre prevention pre pre vention and and develop guidelines in order to assist<br />

the Member States in the preparation <strong>of</strong> the Programmes. 3<br />

Article Article 30<br />

30<br />

Evaluation and review <strong>of</strong> plans and programmes<br />

1. 1. Member States shall ensure that the waste management plans and waste<br />

prevention programmes are evaluated at least every sixth year and revised as<br />

appropriate and, where relevant, in accordance with Articles 9 and 11 .<br />

2. The European Environment Agency is invited to include in its annual report<br />

a review <strong>of</strong> progress in the completion and implementation <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

prevention programmes.<br />

Article Article 31<br />

31<br />

Public participation<br />

Member States shall ensure that relevant stakeholders and authorities and<br />

the general public have the opportunity to participate in the elaboration <strong>of</strong> the<br />

waste management plans and waste prevention programmes, and have<br />

access to them once elaborated, in accordance with Directive 2003/35/EC<br />

or, if relevant, Directive 2001/42/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Council <strong>of</strong> 27 June 2001 on the assessment <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> certain plans<br />

and programmes on the environment. They shall place the plans and<br />

programmes on a publicly available website.”<br />

The measures referred to in Article 29 as being set out in Annex IV are shown in Box 1<br />

below. 4<br />

Box 1: Annex IV <strong>of</strong> the WFD<br />

Examples <strong>of</strong> waste prevention measures referred to in Article 29<br />

Measures that can affect the framework conditions related to the generation <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

1. The use <strong>of</strong> planning measures, or other economic instruments promoting the efficient use <strong>of</strong> resources.<br />

2. The promotion <strong>of</strong> research and development into the area <strong>of</strong> achieving cleaner and less wasteful products<br />

and technologies and the dissemination and use <strong>of</strong> the results <strong>of</strong> such research and development.<br />

3. The development <strong>of</strong> effective and meaningful indicators <strong>of</strong> the environmental pressures associated with<br />

the generation <strong>of</strong> waste aimed at contributing to the prevention <strong>of</strong> waste generation at all levels, from product<br />

comparisons at Community level through action by local authorities to national measures.<br />

Measures that can affect the design and production and distribution phase<br />

4. The promotion <strong>of</strong> eco-design (the systematic integration <strong>of</strong> environmental aspects into product design with<br />

the aim to improve the environmental performance <strong>of</strong> the product throughout its whole life cycle).<br />

5. The provision <strong>of</strong> information on waste prevention techniques with a view to facilitating the implementation<br />

<strong>of</strong> best available techniques by industry.<br />

6. Organise training <strong>of</strong> competent authorities as regards the insertion <strong>of</strong> waste prevention requirements in<br />

permits under this Directive and Directive 96/61/EC.<br />

3 The European Commission has already initiated the process <strong>of</strong> developing these Guidelines.<br />

4 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and the Council <strong>of</strong> 19 November 2008 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Repealing Certain Directives.


7. The inclusion <strong>of</strong> measures to prevent waste production at installations not falling under Directive 96/61/EC.<br />

Where appropriate, such measures could include waste prevention assessments or plans.<br />

8. The use <strong>of</strong> awareness campaigns or the provision <strong>of</strong> financial, decision making or other support to<br />

businesses. Such measures are likely to be particularly effective where they are aimed at, and adapted to,<br />

small and medium sized enterprises and work through established business networks.<br />

9. The use <strong>of</strong> voluntary agreements, consumer/producer panels or sectoral negotiations in order that the<br />

relevant businesses or industrial sectors set their own waste prevention plans or objectives or correct<br />

wasteful products or packaging.<br />

10. The promotion <strong>of</strong> creditable environmental management systems, including EMAS and ISO 14001.<br />

Measures that can affect the consumption and use phase<br />

11. Economic instruments such as incentives for clean purchases or the institution <strong>of</strong> an obligatory payment<br />

by consumers for a given article or element <strong>of</strong> packaging that would otherwise be provided free <strong>of</strong> charge.<br />

12. The use <strong>of</strong> awareness campaigns and information provision directed at the general public or a specific<br />

set <strong>of</strong> consumers.<br />

13. The promotion <strong>of</strong> creditable eco-labels.<br />

14. Agreements with industry, such as the use <strong>of</strong> product panels such as those being carried out within the<br />

framework <strong>of</strong> Integrated Product Policies or with retailers on the availability <strong>of</strong> waste prevention information<br />

and products with a lower environmental impact.<br />

15. In the context <strong>of</strong> public and corporate procurement, the integration <strong>of</strong> environmental and waste<br />

prevention criteria into calls for tenders and contracts, in line with the Handbook on environmental public<br />

procurement published by the Commission on 29 October 2004.<br />

16. The promotion <strong>of</strong> the reuse and/or repair <strong>of</strong> appropriate discarded products or <strong>of</strong> their components,<br />

notably through the use <strong>of</strong> educational, economic, logistic or other measures such as support to or<br />

establishment <strong>of</strong> accredited repair and reuse-centres and networks especially in densely populated regions.<br />

It is clear from the above – the position <strong>of</strong> waste prevention in the hierarchy, and the<br />

need to develop waste prevention programmes, both flowing from the revised WFD –<br />

that waste prevention is beginning to attract growing attention as an area that needs<br />

to be tackled by policy makers. The concept <strong>of</strong> ‘decoupling’ the level <strong>of</strong> activity in the<br />

economy from the level <strong>of</strong> waste being generated is a prominent one, and reflects<br />

concerns that economic growth is not yet on what might be considered to be a<br />

sustainable trajectory. To this end, the WFD includes provision, under Article 9, for<br />

decoupling objectives to be set: 5<br />

5<br />

“The Commission shall, following the consultation <strong>of</strong> stakeholders, submit to<br />

the European Parliament and the Council the following reports accompanied,<br />

if appropriate, by proposals for measures required in support <strong>of</strong> the prevention<br />

activities and the implementation <strong>of</strong> the waste prevention programmes<br />

referred to in Article 29 covering:<br />

a) by the end <strong>of</strong> 2011 an interim report on the evolution <strong>of</strong> waste generation<br />

and the scope <strong>of</strong> waste prevention;<br />

(aa) by the end <strong>of</strong> 2011 the formulation <strong>of</strong> a product eco-design policy<br />

addressing both the generation <strong>of</strong> waste and the presence <strong>of</strong> hazardous<br />

substances in waste, with a view to promoting technologies focusing on<br />

durable, re-usable and recyclable products;<br />

5 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and the Council <strong>of</strong> 19 November 2008 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Repealing Certain Directives.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


6<br />

29/09/09<br />

b) by by by the the the end end end <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> 2014 2014 2014 the the the setting setting setting <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> waste waste waste prev prevention prev prevention<br />

ention and and and decoupling decoupling<br />

decoupling<br />

objectives objectives for for 2020, 2020, based based on on on best best available available practices practices including, including, including, if if necessary,<br />

necessary,<br />

a a revision revision <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the the indicators indicators referred referred to to in in Article Article 29(4) 29(4); 29(4)<br />

c) by the end <strong>of</strong> 2011 the formulation <strong>of</strong> an action plan for further support<br />

measures at European level seeking in particular to change the current<br />

consumption patterns.”<br />

Evidently, if Irish policy and strategy development is to be future-pro<strong>of</strong>ed, the issue <strong>of</strong><br />

waste prevention and decoupling waste generation from economic growth needs to<br />

be considered.<br />

1.2 Definitions<br />

The definition <strong>of</strong> ‘prevention’ has been a matter <strong>of</strong> some debate. The OECD defines<br />

waste prevention as covering the top three elements <strong>of</strong> the standard waste hierarchy,<br />

describing these as: 6<br />

� Strict Strict Strict avoidance avoidance avoidance - the complete prevention <strong>of</strong> waste generation by virtual<br />

elimination <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances or by reducing material or energy<br />

intensity in production, consumption, and distribution.<br />

� Reduction Reduction Reduction at at source source - minimising use <strong>of</strong> toxic or harmful substances and/or<br />

minimising material or energy consumption.<br />

� Product Product Product re re-use re use use - the multiple use <strong>of</strong> a product in its original form, for its original<br />

purpose or for an alternative, with or without reconditioning.<br />

Other studies expand on this definition to include the following examples: 7<br />

“Household waste prevention is minimising the quantity (weight and volume)<br />

and hazardousness <strong>of</strong> household-derived waste generated in a defined<br />

community for collection by any party.<br />

The following activities are included:<br />

Avoidance;<br />

Avoidance;<br />

for example by eliminating hazardous components and substances, by<br />

not purchasing unnecessary goods, by buying services or experiences<br />

rather than goods, by using refill systems and by preventing delivery <strong>of</strong><br />

unwanted mail.<br />

Reduction;<br />

Reduction;<br />

for example by buying less hazardous goods, by purchasing less heavily<br />

packaged goods and goods that are lighter, more compact and more<br />

durable.<br />

6 OECD (2000) Strategic <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention: OECD Reference Manual, Paris: OECD<br />

7 Enviros and Momenta (2005) Towards a UK Framework for Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention, Phase 1<br />

Report for the National Resources & <strong>Waste</strong> Forum.


7<br />

Reuse; Reuse;<br />

Reuse;<br />

for example domestic reuse <strong>of</strong> containers, donation <strong>of</strong> goods to<br />

charities, refurbishment and reuse <strong>of</strong> goods (not-for-pr<strong>of</strong>it or<br />

commercially), home and community composting.”<br />

Centralised composting and energy recovery were excluded, but home composting<br />

was included.<br />

These definitions might be considered, for the purposes <strong>of</strong> developing Irish policy, to<br />

have been superseded by what has now been agreed in the new <strong>Waste</strong> Framework<br />

Directive (WFD). Article 3 sets out the following Definitions <strong>of</strong> relevance to ‘waste<br />

prevention’: 8<br />

"‘Prevention’ means measures taken before a substance, material or product<br />

has become waste, that reduce:<br />

(a) the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste, including through the re-use <strong>of</strong> products or the<br />

extension <strong>of</strong> life-span <strong>of</strong> products;<br />

(b) the adverse impacts <strong>of</strong> the generated waste on the environment and<br />

human health; or<br />

(c) the content <strong>of</strong> harmful substances in materials and products;”<br />

Since prevention includes re-use:<br />

"‘Re-use’ means any operation by which products or components that are not<br />

waste are used again for the same purpose for which they were conceived;<br />

‘Preparing for re-use’ means checking, cleaning or repairing recovery<br />

operations, by which products or components <strong>of</strong> products that have become<br />

waste are prepared so that they will be re-used without any other preprocessing;”<br />

Given that Ireland will have to align its legislation with these requirements, it seems<br />

only logical to use the definitions set out in the revised WFD.<br />

It is, <strong>of</strong> course, important to note that a reduction in waste collected by a local<br />

authority does not necessarily imply that ‘waste prevention’ has occurred to an<br />

equivalent degree (for example, where waste is dumped or burnt illegally).<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the previous debates within the context <strong>of</strong> waste prevention related to how<br />

one should consider measures which reduce the hazardousness <strong>of</strong> waste through<br />

increasing the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste (for example, using vitrification, or stabilisation in<br />

cement). The Commission’s definition appears to address this by including the clause<br />

‘measures taken before a substance, material or product has become waste’ In other<br />

words, measures which reduce hazardousness after a waste has been generated<br />

would not be considered ‘waste prevention’.<br />

8 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and the Council <strong>of</strong> 19 November 2008 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Repealing Certain Directives.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


1.3 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> – Links to Measurement <strong>of</strong> Success<br />

Our experience <strong>of</strong> assessing waste prevention policy is that the almost universally<br />

agreed ‘priority status’ given to waste prevention, reflected in its place at the top <strong>of</strong><br />

the waste hierarchy, is not reflected in the way policy has been developed. Most <strong>of</strong><br />

the influential policies that are addressed to ‘waste’ are not designed to address<br />

waste prevention directly. Rather, they seek to reduce the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste disposed,<br />

or increase its recycling, and sometimes, its recovery. This experience is reinforced in<br />

the review <strong>of</strong> policy undertaken within this report. As regards policies, waste<br />

prevention has not been given the status it deserves. This may be a reflection <strong>of</strong> the<br />

fact that waste policy is influenced by those associated with the management <strong>of</strong><br />

waste. <strong>Waste</strong> prevention is clearly an activity that diminishes the activity <strong>of</strong> those<br />

involved in ‘managing waste’.<br />

The negotiations around the WFD itself included debates around waste prevention<br />

targets and whether they should be set in the WFD. Notwithstanding the clear<br />

agreement on the place <strong>of</strong> waste prevention at the top <strong>of</strong> the hierarchy, policy<br />

makers’ commitment to establishing targets for this is clearly somewhat weak. The<br />

usual argument, rarely challenged (and hence, even more rarely requiring a sensible<br />

defence) is that waste prevention is ‘not measurable’ because one is seeking to<br />

measure ‘something which is no longer there’.<br />

This absence <strong>of</strong> imagination and creativity in the quest to understand how one might<br />

measure waste prevention perhaps explains, in part, the absence <strong>of</strong> relevant policies<br />

themselves. There is an urgent need, therefore, for more cool-headed and creative<br />

thinking about:<br />

8<br />

1. Indicators for measuring success <strong>of</strong> a programme <strong>of</strong> waste prevention; and<br />

2. Means to evaluate the contribution <strong>of</strong> specific measures.<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> the former, some discussion is provided below. In the case <strong>of</strong> the latter,<br />

it seems entirely likely that the approach has to be tailored to fit the policy. Otherwise,<br />

similar rules and guidelines apply as for any ex post assessment <strong>of</strong> any policy. Just<br />

because a policy refers to ‘waste prevention’, this does not mean that the only way to<br />

evaluate its effectiveness is to measure ‘what is no longer there’. As with all ex post<br />

evaluations, the real issue relates to devising a mechanism to evaluate the policy<br />

against a relevant counterfactual scenario. ‘What is no longer there’ is then estimated<br />

‘by subtraction’ using the situation as it now stands, and the situation as it would<br />

have been without the policy in place.<br />

1.3.1 Measuring Decoupling<br />

Prevention policies are typically responses to observed pressures, and require<br />

indicators to measure the success <strong>of</strong> the policy in terms <strong>of</strong> the response. There are<br />

different strategies open to understand the impact <strong>of</strong> the policy. However, what is<br />

essential is to understand the link between changes in waste quantities /<br />

hazardousness <strong>of</strong> waste and the policy itself.<br />

Decoupling means that the link between economic growth and the growth <strong>of</strong> the<br />

environmental problem (or pressure) is broken. According to the OECD “relative<br />

decoupling” means that the economy grows faster than the environmental problem,<br />

29/09/09


ut both grow. “Absolute decoupling” means that the economy grows and the<br />

environmental problem declines. “Negative decoupling” implies that the<br />

environmental problem grows faster than the economy (in other words, there is no<br />

decoupling).<br />

The goal <strong>of</strong> prevention ought to be to achieve absolute decoupling, and to achieve a<br />

reduction in environmental pressure so as to ensure that future environmental quality<br />

is safeguarded, and environmental stocks are effectively managed for the long-term.<br />

The latter is not so easy to define. Hence, an important indicator will inevitably be the<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> the degree <strong>of</strong> decoupling, because <strong>of</strong> the attention paid in Article 9,<br />

Article 29 (see above) and in the preamble (para 40) <strong>of</strong> the new WFD (see above).<br />

Point 3 <strong>of</strong> Annex IV refers to pressure related indicators (see Box 1).<br />

One formulation <strong>of</strong> a decoupling indicator r(t) for a given year t vis-à-vis a given<br />

reference year t0 is as follows: 9<br />

m(<br />

t)<br />

m(<br />

t0)<br />

r ( t)<br />

=<br />

a(<br />

t)<br />

a(<br />

t )<br />

9<br />

0<br />

where m(t) describes the environmental pressure in year t and a(t) describes the<br />

economic variable in year t (and similarly for time t= t0). In circumstances where the<br />

economic indicator is increasing, positive decoupling can be said to occur when the<br />

decoupling indicator is less than one. Absolute decoupling occurs when the<br />

numerator is less than one even where the economic indicator is greater than one.<br />

There is no decoupling when the indicator equals one. When the decoupling indicator<br />

is greater than one, then where the denominator is greater than one, there is negative<br />

decoupling. These rules have to be reconsidered in the context where the economy is<br />

in decline.<br />

In order to take into account the uncertainty factor in the estimations, a hypothesis<br />

test is needed when trying to determine whether or not there is decoupling. The<br />

uncertainty on the data for an individual production year can be relatively high, which<br />

complicates the estimate <strong>of</strong> decoupling. For that reason, the numerator and the<br />

denominator in the equation can be replaced by the inclination <strong>of</strong> a regression line,<br />

which <strong>of</strong>fers greater reliability and robustness than the estimate for a separate year. 10<br />

This methodology has been applied on Flemish data on waste production. Figure 1-1<br />

shows, as an example the decoupling indicator for the total production <strong>of</strong> industrial<br />

waste compared to the GDP for the periods: 1996-2000, 1997-2001, 1998-2002,<br />

1999-2003, 2000-2004, 2001-2005. 11<br />

9 Mike Van Acoleyen (2004) Indicators for <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention - Development <strong>of</strong> a Methodology for, and<br />

Testing <strong>of</strong> OECD Indicators, OVAM: Mechelen.<br />

10 J. Van Dijck (2004) Hypothese testen van indicatoren voor het afvalst<strong>of</strong>beleid, Probabilitas,<br />

Heverlee.<br />

11 OVAM (2008) Bedrijfsafvalst<strong>of</strong>fen: Cijfers en Trends voor Productie, Verwerking, Invoer en Uitvoer,.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


For each indicator decoupling was calculated by comparing the regression <strong>of</strong> the<br />

pressure indicator (in this case waste production) with the economic indicator (in this<br />

case GDP) over the same period. Confidence intervals have been added to see if the<br />

indicator really is statistically sound above zero, which was the case until 2001. From<br />

2002 onwards, positive decoupling cannot with statistical certainty be proved for the<br />

Flemish region.<br />

Figure 1-1: Decoupling Indicator for Industrial <strong>Waste</strong> in Flanders<br />

In principle, the above formulation might be a little simplistic and a more general form<br />

might be:<br />

r =<br />

10<br />

( ∂m<br />

) ∂t<br />

( ∂a<br />

)<br />

29/09/09<br />

∂t<br />

This effectively compares the rate at which the pressure variable is changing over<br />

time relative to the rate <strong>of</strong> change in the economic variable.<br />

The somewhat hackneyed view that waste prevention ‘cannot be measured’ can be<br />

seen to be little more than an excuse not to act, or not to evaluate policies which,<br />

after all, are the ones which ought to be given the highest priority, both because <strong>of</strong><br />

their potential to reduce the waste <strong>of</strong> ‘other factors <strong>of</strong> production’ (solid wastes are<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten a symptom <strong>of</strong> other forms <strong>of</strong> waste), and because <strong>of</strong> their likely positive impact<br />

in terms <strong>of</strong> the environment and sustainable development. Finally, waste prevention<br />

measures frequently give rise to cost savings to businesses and consumers,<br />

suggesting that policy is failing to move these actors to a situation where waste is<br />

considered to be a variable cost in the production process.


1.4 <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling and Composting / Anaerobic Digestion<br />

The WFD defines ‘recycling’ as follows: 12<br />

11<br />

"recycling" means any recovery operation by which waste materials are<br />

reprocessed into products, materials or substances whether for the original or<br />

other purposes. It includes the reprocessing <strong>of</strong> organic material but does not<br />

include energy recovery and the reprocessing into materials that are to be<br />

used as fuels or for backfilling operations.<br />

As such, for the purposes <strong>of</strong> this report, we consider recycling to include the<br />

composting and anaerobic digestion <strong>of</strong> waste where this leads to the production <strong>of</strong> a<br />

useful output.<br />

Article 4(1), which sets out the waste hierarchy, places recycling below ‘prevention’<br />

and ‘preparing for re-use’, but above ‘other recovery’. Article 4(2) suggests that other<br />

than where life-cycle thinking suggests otherwise, recycling should be encouraged<br />

more strongly than either ‘other recovery’ or ‘disposal’, but not at the expense <strong>of</strong><br />

‘prevention’ and ‘preparing for re-use’.<br />

Article 10 states that:<br />

1. Member States shall take the necessary measures to ensure that waste<br />

undergoes recovery operations, in accordance with Articles 4 and 13.<br />

2. Where necessary to comply with paragraph 1 and to facilitate or improve<br />

recovery, waste shall be collected separately if technically, environmentally<br />

and economically practicable and shall not be mixed with other waste or other<br />

material with different properties.<br />

Whereas this does not establish any specific targets, Article 11, on Re-use and<br />

Recycling, states that:<br />

1. Member States shall take measures as appropriate to promote the re-use<br />

<strong>of</strong> products and preparing for re-use activities, notably through encouraging<br />

the establishment and support <strong>of</strong> re-use and repair networks, the use <strong>of</strong><br />

economic instruments, procurement criteria, quantitative objectives or other<br />

measures.<br />

Member States shall take measures to promote high quality recycling and to<br />

this end they shall set up separate collection <strong>of</strong> waste where technically,<br />

environmentally and economically practicable and appropriate to meet the<br />

necessary quality standards for the relevant recycling sectors.<br />

Subject to Article 10(2), by 2015 separate collection shall be set up for at<br />

least the following: paper, metal, plastic and glass.<br />

2. In order to comply with the objectives <strong>of</strong> this Directive, and to move towards<br />

a European recycling society with a high level <strong>of</strong> resource efficiency, Member<br />

12 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and the Council <strong>of</strong> 19 November 2008 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Repealing Certain Directives.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


12<br />

29/09/09<br />

States shall take the necessary measures designed to achieve the following<br />

targets:<br />

a) by 2020 the preparing for re-use and the recycling <strong>of</strong> waste materials such as at<br />

least paper, metal, plastic and glass from households and possibly from other<br />

origins as far as these waste streams are similar to waste from households,<br />

shall be increased to a minimum <strong>of</strong> overall 50% by weight;<br />

b) by 2020 the preparing for re-use, recycling and other material recovery,<br />

including backfilling operations using waste to substitute other materials, <strong>of</strong><br />

non-hazardous construction and demolition waste excluding naturally occurring<br />

material defined in category 17 05 04 in the European <strong>Waste</strong> Catalogue (EWC)<br />

shall be increased to a minimum <strong>of</strong> 70% by weight.<br />

3. The Commission shall, in accordance with the regulatory procedure with<br />

scrutiny referred to in Article 39(2) <strong>of</strong> this Directive, establish detailed rules on<br />

the application and calculation methods for verifying compliance with the<br />

targets set out in paragraph 2 <strong>of</strong> this Article, considering Regulation (EC) No<br />

2150/2002 <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 25 November<br />

2002 on waste statistics. These can include transition periods for Member<br />

States with less than 5% recycling in either category in 2008.<br />

4. By 31 December 2014 at the latest, the Commission shall examine the<br />

measures and the targets referred to in paragraph 2 with a view to, if<br />

necessary, reinforcing the targets and consider setting targets for other waste<br />

streams. The report <strong>of</strong> the Commission, accompanied by a proposal if<br />

appropriate, shall be sent to the European Parliament and the Council. In its<br />

report the Commission shall take into account the relevant environmental,<br />

economic and social impacts <strong>of</strong> setting the targets.<br />

5. Every three years, in accordance with Article 37, Member States shall<br />

report to the Commission on their record with regard to meeting the targets. If<br />

targets are not met, this report shall include the reasons for failure and the<br />

actions the Member State intends to take to meet the targets.<br />

Eunomia, as leaders in this study, is involved in work referred to under paragraph 3<br />

above. This is being led by the Oko Institut. For the time being, the Commission has<br />

issued, in response to a request to the United Kingdom, clarification <strong>of</strong> paragraph 2<br />

above (which is far from being unambiguous). The Commission stated: 13<br />

It is also the Commission services' understanding that the 50% target applies<br />

to the totality <strong>of</strong> at least four material waste streams including paper, plastics,<br />

glass and metals originating from households and possibly other sources, and<br />

does not apply individually to each <strong>of</strong> these waste streams. By "the totality" <strong>of</strong><br />

wastes we understand the amount <strong>of</strong> both separately collected and mixed<br />

13 Response from Commisioner, DG Environment, to letter from Roy Hathaway, Defra, dated 31 July<br />

2008.


13<br />

waste from these sources. Member States can add more material waste<br />

streams from household or similar wastes to this target (e.g. biowaste) in<br />

which case the 50% target would apply to the totality <strong>of</strong> all waste streams<br />

included. I would also like to draw your attention to Article 11(3) <strong>of</strong> the draft<br />

revised <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive which specifies that any eventual<br />

modalities related to the application and calculation methods for verifying<br />

compliance with the targets need to be elaborated by the Commission and the<br />

Member States in comitology.<br />

The most recent EPA report suggests that recycling rates for the four materials under<br />

consideration paper, metal, plastic, glass, was such that the target would be met for<br />

each <strong>of</strong> metals, paper and glass, but not plastic (see Table 1-1). The target would be<br />

met if one aggregated the figures for all 4 materials.<br />

The picture is quite different if one looks only at household waste (see Table 1-2).<br />

Here, the 50% target is not met for the materials in combination. The target is just<br />

exceeded for paper, it is easily exceeded for glass, but in respect <strong>of</strong> plastics and<br />

metals, the performance is below what is suggested.<br />

Pending the agreement <strong>of</strong> rules described in para 3 above, Ireland would appear to<br />

be already meeting targets for municipal waste, though the hierarchy and Article 10<br />

should still be followed, subject to life-cycle thinking suggesting otherwise. Hence, the<br />

target under the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive should be considered a bare minimum,<br />

and in any case, it may yet be supplemented by a requirement to separate biowaste<br />

at source.<br />

Table 1-1: Recycling Performance for 4 Key WFD Materials, Municipal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Managed Managed<br />

Managed Landfilled Landfilled<br />

Landfilled Recycled<br />

Recycled Recycled<br />

Recycled<br />

(tonnes)<br />

(tonnes) (tonnes)<br />

(tonnes) (tonnes)<br />

(tonnes) (%)<br />

(%)<br />

Metals 133,500 50,000 83,499 62.5%<br />

Paper 914,069 384,245 529,824 58.0%<br />

Plastic 288,760 223,755 65,005 22.5%<br />

Glass 182,554 48,075 134,479 73.7%<br />

Total 1,518,883 706,075 812,807 53.5%<br />

Source: EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Wexford: EPA.<br />

Table 1-2: Recycling Performance for 4 Key WFD Materials, Household <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Managed Managed<br />

Managed Landfilled<br />

Landfilled Recycled<br />

Recycled Recycled<br />

Recycled<br />

(tonnes)<br />

(tonnes) (tonnes) (tonnes)<br />

(tonnes) (tonnes) (tonnes)<br />

(tonnes) (%)<br />

(%)<br />

Metals 48,021 35,577 12,444 25.9%<br />

Paper 385,074 187,350 197,724 51.3%<br />

Plastic 195,881 153,662 42,219 21.6%<br />

Glass 131,300 38,759 92,540 70.5%<br />

Total 760,276 415,348 344,927 45.4%<br />

Source: EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Wexford: EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


As regards the WFD 70% target for re-use, recycling and recovery for construction and<br />

demolition waste, the latest EPA report indicates that Ireland is already achieving this<br />

target. Some caveats are necessary here, however, not least since the EPA Report<br />

highlights problems with the data. This is likely to be true in cases other than Ireland,<br />

and the challenge for many Member States will be to obtain quality data as to their<br />

current performance, not to mention that in the future.<br />

It will be clear that the above targets relate in the main to dry materials. The WFD also<br />

highlights the significance <strong>of</strong> the biowaste stream in Article 22, which states:<br />

14<br />

29/09/09<br />

Member States shall take measures, as appropriate, and in accordance with<br />

Articles 4 and 13, to encourage:<br />

a) the separate collection <strong>of</strong> bio-waste with a view to the composting<br />

and digestion <strong>of</strong> bio-waste;<br />

b) the treatment <strong>of</strong> bio-waste in a way that fulfils a high level <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental protection;<br />

c) the use <strong>of</strong> environmentally safe materials produced from bio-waste.<br />

The Commission shall carry out an assessment on the management <strong>of</strong> biowaste<br />

with a view to submitting a proposal if appropriate.<br />

The assessment shall examine the opportunity <strong>of</strong> setting minimum<br />

requirements for bio-waste management and quality criteria for compost and<br />

digestate from bio-waste, in order to guarantee a high level <strong>of</strong> protection for<br />

human health and the environment.<br />

In respect <strong>of</strong> the Commission’s above commitment, the Commission has already<br />

issued a Green Paper on the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> Biowaste in the European Union. This<br />

asks a number <strong>of</strong> questions pertinent to the management <strong>of</strong> biowaste, and ends with<br />

the statement that: 14<br />

In late 2009, the Commission intends to present its analysis <strong>of</strong> the responses<br />

received together with, if appropriate, its proposals and/or initiatives for an EU<br />

strategy on the management <strong>of</strong> bio-waste.<br />

Ireland’s performance in respect <strong>of</strong> biowaste is far worse than on many <strong>of</strong> the dry<br />

recyclables. The latest EPA Report suggests that less than one tenth <strong>of</strong> the estimated<br />

918 thousand tonnes <strong>of</strong> organic waste was recovered. This stream has been the<br />

focus <strong>of</strong> much recent activity in the policy area. Circular WPPR 17/08 on the<br />

Implementation <strong>of</strong> Segregated ‘Brown Bin’ Collection for Biowaste and Home<br />

Composting was issued on 31 July 2008 to all City and County Managers. This affects<br />

the provision <strong>of</strong> separate collection services to households. More recently,<br />

consultation has been launched on a new Statutory Instrument, the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

14 Commission <strong>of</strong> the European Communities (2008) Green Paper on the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> Biowaste in<br />

the European Union, COM(2008) 811 Final, Brussels, 3.12.08 (available at http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2008:0811:FIN:EN:PDF).


<strong>Management</strong> (Food <strong>Waste</strong>) Regulations. This would effectively mandate the separate<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> food waste from waste producers, as defined under the instrument.<br />

Another important feature <strong>of</strong> the WFD, which is pertinent to the recycling <strong>of</strong> biowaste,<br />

is Article 6, which concerns the matter <strong>of</strong> whether, and if so, when, waste might cease<br />

to be treated as such (the ‘end <strong>of</strong> waste’ issues). The Article states: 15<br />

15<br />

1. Certain specified waste shall cease to be waste within the meaning <strong>of</strong> point<br />

(1) <strong>of</strong> Article 3 when it has undergone a recovery, , , including including recycling, recycling,<br />

operation and complies with specific criteria to be developed in accordance<br />

with the following conditions:<br />

a) the substance or object is commonly used for specific purposes purposes purposes ;<br />

b) a market or demand exists for such a substance or object;<br />

c) the substance or object fulfils the technical requirements for the<br />

specific purposes purposes and meets the existing legislation and standards<br />

applicable to products; and<br />

d) the use <strong>of</strong> the substance or object will not lead to overall adverse<br />

environmental or human health impacts.<br />

The criteria shall include limit values for pollutants where necessary and and shall<br />

shall<br />

take take into into account account account any any any possible possible advers adverse advers e environmental environmental environmental effects effects effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

the<br />

substance substance substance or or object object. object<br />

2. The measures relating to the adoption <strong>of</strong> such criteria and specifying the<br />

waste, designed to amend non-essential elements <strong>of</strong> this Directive, by<br />

supplementing it, shall be adopted in accordance with the regulatory<br />

procedure with scrutiny referred to in Article 39 (2). End End-<strong>of</strong> End <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>-waste <strong>of</strong> waste specific<br />

specific<br />

criteria criteria should should be be be considered, considered, among among others, others, at at least least for for aggregates, aggregates, paper,<br />

paper,<br />

glass, glass, glass, metal, metal, metal, tyres tyres and textiles.<br />

3. <strong>Waste</strong> which ceases to be waste in accordance with paragraphs 1 and 2,<br />

shall also cease to be waste for the purpose <strong>of</strong> the recovery and recycling<br />

targets set out in Directives 94/62/EC, 2000/53/EC, 2002/96/EC and<br />

2006/66/EC and other relevant Community legislation when the recycling or or<br />

recovery recovery requirements requirements o<strong>of</strong><br />

o f that legislation are are met met. met<br />

4. Where criteria have not been set at Community level under the procedure<br />

set out in paragraphs 1 and 2, Member States may decide case by case<br />

whether certain waste has ceased to be waste taking into account the<br />

applicable case law. They shall notify the Commission <strong>of</strong> such decisions in<br />

accordance with Directive 98/34/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Council <strong>of</strong> 22 June 1998 laying down a procedure for the provision <strong>of</strong><br />

information in the field <strong>of</strong> technical standards and regulations and <strong>of</strong> rules on<br />

Information Society services where so required by that Directive.<br />

15 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and the Council <strong>of</strong> 19 November 2008 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Repealing Certain Directives.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The Joint Research Centre (JRC) <strong>of</strong> the European Commission has been leading pilot<br />

studies on end-<strong>of</strong>-waste criteria for aggregates and for biowaste. A report has been<br />

published on the JRC website concerning the study. 16<br />

As far as recycling is concerned, the WFD effectively underpins the Producer<br />

Responsibility Directives already in place. These are:<br />

16<br />

� European Parliament and Council Directive 94/62/EC <strong>of</strong> 20 December 1994<br />

on packaging and packaging waste 17;<br />

� Directive 2000/53/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong><br />

18 September 2000 on end-<strong>of</strong> life vehicles; 18<br />

� Directive 2002/96/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 27<br />

January 2003 on waste electrical and electronic equipment<br />

(WEEE); 19http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=-<br />

//EP//TEXT+TA+P6-TA-2008-0282+0+DOC+XML+V0//EN&language=EN -<br />

def_2_14#def_2_14 and<br />

� Directive 2006/66/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong><br />

6 September 2006 on batteries and accumulators and waste batteries and<br />

accumulators. 20<br />

Article 8 <strong>of</strong> the WFD, on Extended Producer Responsibility, allows Member States<br />

considerable freedom to develop measures to encourage producers to take<br />

responsibility for their products. The ambition <strong>of</strong> Member State measures is certainly<br />

not restricted to those products already covered by EU Directives. The Article seems<br />

designed to allow Member States to develop their own initiatives in this regard (as<br />

some have done already – see Annex 15.0): 21<br />

29/09/09<br />

1. In order to strengthen the prevention, re-use, recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong><br />

waste, Member States may take legislative or non-legislative measures to<br />

ensure that any natural or legal person who pr<strong>of</strong>essionally develops,<br />

manufactures, processes, treats, sells or imports products (producer <strong>of</strong> the<br />

product) has extended producer responsibility.<br />

16 JRC (2009) End <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Criteria, JRC Scientific and Technical Reports,<br />

http://susproc.jrc.ec.europa.eu/activities/waste/documents/End<strong>of</strong>wastecriteriafinal.pdf<br />

17 OJ L 365, 31.12.1994, p. 10. Directive as last amended by Directive 2005/20/EC (OJ L 70,<br />

16.3.2005, p. 17).<br />

18 OJ L 269, 21.10.2000, p. 34. Directive as last amended by Directive 2008/33/EC <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council (OJ L 81, 20.3.2008, p. 62 ).<br />

19 OJ L 37, 13.2.2003, p. 24. Directive as last amended by Directive 2008/34/EC (OJ L 81,<br />

20.3.2008, p. 65).<br />

20 OJ L 266, 26.9.2006, p. 1. Directive as last amended by Directive 2008/12/EC (OJ L 76,<br />

19.3.2008, p. 39).<br />

21 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and the Council <strong>of</strong> 19 November 2008 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Repealing Certain Directives.


17<br />

Such measures may include an acceptance <strong>of</strong> returned products and <strong>of</strong> the<br />

waste that remains after those products have been used, as well as the<br />

subsequent management <strong>of</strong> the waste and financial responsibility for such<br />

activities. These measures may include the obligation to provide publicly<br />

available information as to the extent to which the product is re-usable and<br />

recyclable.<br />

2. Member States may take appropriate measures to encourage the design <strong>of</strong><br />

products in order to reduce their environmental impacts and the generation <strong>of</strong><br />

waste in the course <strong>of</strong> the production and subsequent use <strong>of</strong> products, and in<br />

order to ensure that the recovery and disposal <strong>of</strong> products that have become<br />

waste take place in accordance with Articles 4 and 13.<br />

Such measures may encourage, inter alia, the development, production and<br />

marketing <strong>of</strong> products that are suitable for multiple use, that are technically<br />

durable and that are, after having become waste, suitable for proper and safe<br />

recovery and environmentally compatible disposal.<br />

When applying extended producer responsibility, Member States shall take<br />

into account the technical feasibility and economic viability and the overall<br />

environmental, human health and social impacts, respecting the need to<br />

ensure the proper functioning <strong>of</strong> the internal market.<br />

4. The extended producer responsibility shall be applied without prejudice to<br />

the responsibility for waste management as provided for in Article 15 (1) and<br />

without prejudice to existing waste stream specific and product specific<br />

legislation.<br />

Article 14 (2), on Costs, bears some relation to Extended Producer Responsibility. It<br />

states that:<br />

2. Member States may decide that the costs <strong>of</strong> waste management are to be<br />

borne partly or wholly by the producer <strong>of</strong> the product from which the waste<br />

came and that the distributors <strong>of</strong> such product may share these costs.<br />

If one takes this principle to its limit, and if one also bears in mind the preamble to<br />

the WFD (which, at Para 26 reiterates the status <strong>of</strong> the polluter pays principle as ‘a<br />

guiding principle at the European and <strong>International</strong> levels’), then where Article 14(1),<br />

states:<br />

1. In accordance with the polluter-pays principle, the costs <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management shall be borne by the original waste producer or by the current<br />

or previous waste holders<br />

one might reasonably interpret the logic to be that where extended producer<br />

responsibility systems are implemented, producers / distributors should bear all costs<br />

related to extended producer responsibility, ensuring that as far as possible,<br />

consumers <strong>of</strong> products – the ultimate causes <strong>of</strong> the pollution – pay.<br />

1.4.1 The Producer Responsibility Directives<br />

The key producer responsibility Directives were listed above. The intention, in what<br />

follows, is not to describe each Directive in detail, but to highlight the key issues<br />

facing Ireland in each <strong>of</strong> these.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


1.4.1.1 Packaging and Packaging <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Directive 94/62/EC <strong>of</strong> 20 December 1994 on packaging and packaging waste , and<br />

its amendments suggests that Member States must introduce systems for the return<br />

and/or collection <strong>of</strong> used packaging to attain specific targets. The targets were recast<br />

so that Member States must achieve the following targets:<br />

18<br />

� by no later than 31 December 2008, between 55 and 80% by weight <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging waste to be recycled;<br />

� no later than 31 December 2008 the following targets for materials contained<br />

in packaging waste must be attained: 60% by weight for glass, paper and<br />

board; 50% by weight for metals; 22.5% by weight for plastics and 15% by<br />

weight for wood; and<br />

� by no later than 31 December 2008, at least 60% by weight <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

waste to be recovered or incinerated at waste incineration plants with energy<br />

recovery;<br />

The Directive also lays down essential requirements with which countries should<br />

comply regarding the composition and the reusable and recoverable nature <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging and packaging waste. The Commission has been critical <strong>of</strong> the way in<br />

which Member States have implemented the essential requirements aspect <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Directive: 22<br />

29/09/09<br />

Although there seems to be some decoupling <strong>of</strong> packaging waste generation<br />

from GDP growth, in almost all Member States the absolute quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging waste is increasing. Prevention measures such as enforcement<br />

systems for the essential requirements, packaging prevention plans and<br />

strong producer responsibility systems might have had some effect on the<br />

reduction <strong>of</strong> packaging generation. However, the overall patterns <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

waste generation are not significantly different between the Member States<br />

applying different prevention tools and the Member States applying none <strong>of</strong><br />

these tools.<br />

It has made clear its determination is to promote the development <strong>of</strong> European<br />

standards relating to these essential requirements and has suggested that provisions<br />

concerning pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> conformity with national standards should be applied<br />

immediately.<br />

1.4.1.2 End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

Directive 2000/53/EC on end-<strong>of</strong> life vehicles seeks to make waste prevention its<br />

priority objective. It stipulates that vehicle manufacturers and material and<br />

equipment manufacturers must:<br />

22 Commission <strong>of</strong> the European Communities (2006) Report from the Commission to the Council and<br />

the European Parliament on the Implementation <strong>of</strong> Directive 94/62/EC on Packaging and Packaging<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> and its Impact on the Environment, as well as Functioning <strong>of</strong> the Internal Market, COM (2006)<br />

767 Final, 6 th December 2006.


19<br />

� endeavour to reduce the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances when designing<br />

vehicles;<br />

� design and produce vehicles which facilitate the dismantling, re-use, recovery<br />

and recycling <strong>of</strong> end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles;<br />

� increase the use <strong>of</strong> recycled materials in vehicle manufacture;<br />

� ensure that components <strong>of</strong> vehicles placed on the market after 1 July 2003 do<br />

not contain mercury, hexavalent chromium, cadmium or lead, except in the<br />

applications listed in Annex II. The Council or the Commission may amend the<br />

Annex where scientific and technical progress make it possible to avoid using<br />

these substances.<br />

The Directive also introduces provisions on the collection <strong>of</strong> all end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles<br />

(Article 5). Member States must set up collection systems for end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles and<br />

for used parts. They must also ensure that all vehicles are transferred to authorised<br />

treatment facilities, and set up a system <strong>of</strong> deregistration upon presentation <strong>of</strong> a<br />

certificate <strong>of</strong> destruction. Such certificates are to be issued when the vehicle is<br />

transferred, free <strong>of</strong> charge, to a treatment facility.<br />

The last holder <strong>of</strong> an end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicle may dispose <strong>of</strong> it free <strong>of</strong> charge ("free takeback"<br />

principle). Producers must meet all, or a significant proportion <strong>of</strong>, the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

this measure.<br />

The storage and treatment <strong>of</strong> end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles is also subject to strict control, in<br />

accordance with the requirements <strong>of</strong> Directive 75/442/EEC replaced by Directive<br />

2006/12/EC and <strong>of</strong> Annex I to the Directive. Establishments or undertakings carrying<br />

out treatment operations must strip end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles before treatment and recover<br />

all environmentally hazardous components. Priority must be given to the re-use and<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> vehicle components (batteries, tyres and oil).<br />

At present, 75% <strong>of</strong> end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles are recycled (metal content). The aim <strong>of</strong> this<br />

Directive is to increase the rate <strong>of</strong> re-use and recovery to 85% in terms <strong>of</strong> average<br />

weight per vehicle/year by 2006, and to 95% by 2015, and to increase the rate <strong>of</strong> reuse<br />

and recycling over the same period to at least 80% and 85% respectively in terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> average weight per vehicle/year. Less stringent objectives may be set for vehicles<br />

produced before 1980.<br />

Member States must ensure that producers use material coding standards which<br />

allow identification <strong>of</strong> the various materials during dismantling. The Commission must<br />

establish European standards on material coding and identification.<br />

Economic operators must provide prospective purchasers <strong>of</strong> vehicles with information<br />

on the recovery and recycling <strong>of</strong> vehicle components, the treatment <strong>of</strong> end-<strong>of</strong>-life<br />

vehicles and progress with regard to re-use, recycling and recovery. On the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

this information, Member States must report to the Commission every three years on<br />

the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Directive. The Commission must then publish a report on<br />

the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Directive.<br />

Member States may incorporate some <strong>of</strong> the Directive's provisions into national law<br />

by means <strong>of</strong> agreements with the economic sectors concerned.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


1.4.1.3 <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment<br />

Directive 2002/96/EC on waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) applies<br />

to the categories <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic equipment listed below, with subcategories<br />

being the business-to-consumer (B2C) stream (which ends up predominantly<br />

in the householder waste stream) and the business-to-business (B2B)<br />

stream.<br />

Category 1 - Large household appliances<br />

Category 2 - Small household appliances<br />

Category 3 - IT & telecoms equipment<br />

Category 4 - Consumer equipment<br />

Category 5 - Lighting equipment<br />

Category 6 - Electrical & electronic tools<br />

Category 7 - Toys, leisure & sports equipment<br />

Category 8 - Medical devices<br />

Category 9 - Monitoring & control equipment<br />

Category 10 - Automatic dispensers<br />

The WEEE directive is quite precise with regard to producer responsibility, specifically<br />

referring to “producers”, providing a definition <strong>of</strong> what constitutes a “producer” and<br />

requiring them to undertake specific actions. Until recently, these actions were as<br />

follows:<br />

1) producers must take into account waste management at the design stage <strong>of</strong> the<br />

product e.g. by making design modifications that make WEEE easier to dismantle,<br />

recycle and recover;<br />

2) producers must guarantee fixed re-use and/or recycling and recovery rates either<br />

individually or via collective organisations (the WEEE directive currently sets a<br />

minimum collection target <strong>of</strong> 4 kg per annum per inhabitant for WEEE from<br />

households);<br />

3) producers are obliged to finance at least the collection, treatment, recovery and<br />

environmentally-sound disposal <strong>of</strong> household WEEE deposited at collection sites;<br />

and<br />

4) for WEEE placed on the market after 13th August 2005, producers are obliged to<br />

finance those operations associated with the waste from their own products/<br />

production processes.<br />

Distributors are also linked to the WEEE producer responsibility via an obligation to<br />

take back products free <strong>of</strong> charge on a ‘one-for-one’ or ‘old-for-new’ basis.<br />

In December 2008, a proposal for revised laws on WEEE was drafted by the European<br />

Commission. The Commission noted that, following implementation <strong>of</strong> the Directive:<br />

20<br />

29/09/09<br />

More than four years later only about a third <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic waste<br />

is reported to be treated in line with these laws and the other two thirds is<br />

going to landfill and potentially to sub-standard treatment sites in or outside


21<br />

the European Union. Apart from losing out on valuable secondary raw<br />

materials, this is especially worrisome since inadequately treated products<br />

pose major environmental and health risks. The illegal trade to non-EU<br />

countries also continues to be widespread. Moreover many electrical and<br />

electronic products not complying with the substance restrictions have been<br />

found in the EU.<br />

With regard to bullet point 2 above, it proposed that the collection target be altered<br />

from 4 kg per annum per inhabitant to a 65% collection rate, calculated according to<br />

the average amount <strong>of</strong> EEE placed on the market in the two preceding years. In<br />

addition, in order to encourage the re-use <strong>of</strong> whole appliances, it is proposed that<br />

such re-use be included within the 65% target. The proposal also goes further than<br />

bullet point 3, suggesting that Member States should, where appropriate, encourage<br />

producers to finance all the cost occurring for collection facilities for business to<br />

consumer WEEE.<br />

1.4.1.4 Batteries and Accumulators and <strong>Waste</strong> Batteries and Accumulators<br />

Directive 2006/66/EC on batteries and accumulators and waste batteries and<br />

accumulators outlines three distinct battery classifications – industrial, automotive<br />

and portable (usually defined as sealed and hand carried). While it is clear which<br />

sector <strong>of</strong> the economy industrial batteries belong, portable batteries are used across<br />

consumer, commercial and industrial sectors (though the vast majority are used in<br />

consumer applications). Automotive batteries also straddle all three sectors.<br />

As noted in the Directive, “batteries” is used to mean single-life batteries (sometimes<br />

also referred to as ‘primary’ batteries), and “accumulators” to mean rechargeable<br />

batteries (sometimes also referred to as ‘secondary’ batteries). In this report<br />

“batteries” is taken to mean both batteries and accumulators, unless otherwise<br />

specified.<br />

The intended impact <strong>of</strong> the Batteries Directive is to improve the environmental<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> batteries and <strong>of</strong> the activities <strong>of</strong> all economic operators involved in<br />

the life cycle <strong>of</strong> batteries. Key provisions <strong>of</strong> the Directive are:<br />

� Restrictions on the use <strong>of</strong> mercury (0.0005%) and cadmium (0.0002%) in all<br />

batteries by weight (with the exception <strong>of</strong> button cells at 2%);<br />

� Labelling requirements for new batteries to aid consumer choice and recycling;<br />

� A 25% collection rate for waste portable batteries to be met by September<br />

2012, rising to 45% by September 2016. Note that the collection rate is not<br />

the same as a recycling rate;<br />

� A prohibition on the disposal by landfill or incineration <strong>of</strong> waste industrial and<br />

automotive batteries – in effect setting a 100% collection and recycling target;<br />

� The introduction <strong>of</strong> “producer responsibility” obligations;<br />

� The setting <strong>of</strong> recycling efficiencies to ensure that a high proportion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

weight <strong>of</strong> waste batteries is recycled (65% <strong>of</strong> lead acid batteries, 75% <strong>of</strong><br />

nickel-cadmium batteries and 50% <strong>of</strong> other waste batteries); and<br />

� The setting <strong>of</strong> waste battery treatment standards.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Member State implementation <strong>of</strong> the Directive reflects these objectives. Member<br />

States must take whatever measures are needed (including economic instruments) to<br />

promote and maximise separate waste collections and prevent batteries and<br />

accumulators being thrown away as unsorted municipal refuse. They have to make<br />

arrangements enabling end-users to discard spent batteries and accumulators at<br />

collection points in their vicinity and have them taken back at no charge by the<br />

producers.<br />

In principle, it must be possible to remove batteries and accumulators readily and<br />

safely. It is for Member States to ensure that manufacturers design their appliances<br />

accordingly.<br />

Member States also have to ensure that, from 26 September 2009 at the latest,<br />

batteries and accumulators that have been collected are treated and recycled using<br />

the best available techniques. Recycling must exclude energy recovery. As a<br />

minimum, treatment must include removal <strong>of</strong> all fluids and acids. Batteries and<br />

accumulators must be treated and stored (even if only temporarily) in sites with<br />

impermeable surfaces and weatherpro<strong>of</strong> covering, or in suitable containers.<br />

If there is no viable end market, or if a detailed assessment <strong>of</strong> environmental,<br />

economic and social impact concludes that recycling is not the best solution, Member<br />

States may dispose <strong>of</strong> batteries and accumulators containing cadmium, mercury or<br />

lead in landfills or underground storage. Otherwise, it is prohibited to put waste from<br />

industrial and automotive batteries and accumulators into landfill, or to incinerate it;<br />

only residues from treating and recycling them may be disposed <strong>of</strong> in these ways.<br />

The producers have to bear the cost <strong>of</strong> collecting, treating and recycling industrial,<br />

automotive and portable batteries and accumulators, as well as the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

campaigns to inform the public <strong>of</strong> these arrangements. Small producers may be<br />

exempted from this obligation if this does not impede the proper functioning <strong>of</strong> the<br />

collection and recycling schemes. All producers <strong>of</strong> batteries and accumulators have to<br />

be registered.<br />

1.5 The Landfill Directive<br />

Article 1 <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive sets out the objective: 23<br />

22<br />

29/09/09<br />

to provide for measures, procedures and guidance to prevent or reduce as far<br />

as possible negative effects on the environment, in particular the pollution <strong>of</strong><br />

surface water, groundwater, soil and air, and on the global environment,<br />

including the greenhouse effect, as well as any resulting risk to human health,<br />

from landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste, during the whole life-cycle <strong>of</strong> the landfill.<br />

Article 5 concerns waste and treatment not acceptable in landfills. Para 1 <strong>of</strong> Art. 5<br />

states: 24<br />

23 Council Directive 1999/31/EC <strong>of</strong> 26 April 1999 on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste Official Journal L 182 ,<br />

16/07/1999.


23<br />

1. Member States shall set up a national strategy for the implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

the reduction <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste going to landfills, not later than two<br />

years after the date laid down in Article 18(1) and notify the Commission <strong>of</strong><br />

this strategy. This strategy should include measures to achieve the targets set<br />

out in paragraph 2 by means <strong>of</strong> in particular, recycling, composting, biogas<br />

production or materials/energy recovery. Within 30 months <strong>of</strong> the date laid<br />

down in Article 18(1) the Commission shall provide the European Parliament<br />

and the Council with a report drawing together the national strategies.<br />

Article 5(2) sets targets for reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste sent to<br />

landfill: 25<br />

2. This strategy shall ensure that:<br />

(a) not later than five years after the date laid down in Article 18(1),<br />

biodegradable municipal waste going to landfills must be reduced to 75 % <strong>of</strong><br />

the total amount (by weight) <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste produced in<br />

1995 or the latest year before 1995 for which standardised Eurostat data is<br />

available<br />

(b) not later than eight years after the date laid down in Article 18(1),<br />

biodegradable municipal waste going to landfills must be reduced to 50 % <strong>of</strong><br />

the total amount (by weight) <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste produced in<br />

1995 or the latest year before 1995 for which standardised Eurostat data is<br />

available;<br />

(c) not later than 15 years after the date laid down in Article 18(1),<br />

biodegradable municipal waste going to landfills must be reduced to 35 % <strong>of</strong><br />

the total amount (by weight) <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste produced in<br />

1995 or the latest year before 1995 for which standardised Eurostat data is<br />

available.<br />

Two years before the date referred to in paragraph (c) the Council shall reexamine<br />

the above target, on the basis <strong>of</strong> a report from the Commission on<br />

the practical experience gained by Member States in the pursuance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

targets laid down in paragraphs (a) and (b) accompanied, if appropriate, by a<br />

proposal with a view to confirming or amending this target in order to ensure a<br />

high level <strong>of</strong> environmental protection.<br />

Member States which in 1995 or the latest year before 1995 for which<br />

standardised EUROSTAT data is available put more than 80 % <strong>of</strong> their<br />

collected municipal waste to landfill may postpone the attainment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

targets set out in paragraphs (a), (b), or (c) by a period not exceeding four<br />

years. Member States intending to make use <strong>of</strong> this provision shall inform in<br />

advance the Commission <strong>of</strong> their decision. The Commission shall inform other<br />

Member States and the European Parliament <strong>of</strong> these decisions.<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the provisions set out in the preceding subparagraph<br />

24 Council Directive 1999/31/EC <strong>of</strong> 26 April 1999 on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste Official Journal L 182 ,<br />

16/07/1999.<br />

25 Council Directive 1999/31/EC <strong>of</strong> 26 April 1999 on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste Official Journal L 182 ,<br />

16/07/1999.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


24<br />

29/09/09<br />

may in no circumstances lead to the attainment <strong>of</strong> the target set out in<br />

paragraph (c) at a date later than four years after the date set out in<br />

paragraph (c).<br />

Article 5(3) effectively bans a range <strong>of</strong> waste from landfill, including waste which does<br />

not meet specific acceptance criteria laid down in Annex II <strong>of</strong> the Directive.<br />

Article 6 concerns waste to be accepted in the different classes <strong>of</strong> landfill, and Art<br />

6(a) is <strong>of</strong> particular significance since it requires that waste must be treated prior to<br />

being landfilled: 26<br />

Member States shall take measures in order that:<br />

(a) only waste that has been subject to treatment is landfilled. This provision<br />

may not apply to inert waste for which treatment is not technically feasible,<br />

nor to any other waste for which such treatment does not contribute to the<br />

objectives <strong>of</strong> this Directive, as set out in Article 1, by reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

the waste or the hazards to human health or the environment;<br />

Article 2 defines treatment as follows: 27<br />

"treatment" means the physical, thermal, chemical or biological processes,<br />

including sorting, that change the characteristics <strong>of</strong> the waste in order to<br />

reduce its volume or hazardous nature, facilitate its handling or enhance<br />

recovery;<br />

Different Member States have interpreted this requirement to treat with varying<br />

degrees <strong>of</strong> vigour. Some have banned many wastes from landfill (and some <strong>of</strong> these<br />

were doing so before the Directive), others have set thresholds for biodegradability<br />

(so as to ensure treatment reduces this to very low levels) and some have adopted<br />

very weak approaches (for example, the UK interprets the Article 2 definition very<br />

generously, and takes the view that any amount <strong>of</strong> separation <strong>of</strong> materials (e.g. use <strong>of</strong><br />

a paper collection) constitutes pre-treatment. The EPA has recently issued Guidance<br />

on how it intends to interpret the requirement to treat. 28 This is discussed in more<br />

detail in Section 51.5.2 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes.<br />

The Directive makes various other important points in respect to the operation <strong>of</strong><br />

landfills, and the recovery <strong>of</strong> costs, including those for aftercare. These requirements,<br />

and their implementation within Ireland, as well as other (pre-Directive) efforts by the<br />

EPA to close down unregulated dumps, have been important in increasing disposal<br />

costs in Ireland from the very low levels <strong>of</strong> the early 1990s.<br />

26 Council Directive 1999/31/EC <strong>of</strong> 26 April 1999 on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste Official Journal L 182 ,<br />

16/07/1999.<br />

27 Council Directive 1999/31/EC <strong>of</strong> 26 April 1999 on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste Official Journal L 182 ,<br />

16/07/1999.<br />

28 EPA (2009) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> - Pre-treatment and Residuals <strong>Management</strong>: An EPA Technical<br />

Guidance Document, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.


1.6 The Incineration Directive<br />

The Directive on the Incineration <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> (‘the waste incineration Directive’, or WID)<br />

was published in 2000. 29 The Directive replaces earlier Directives relating to<br />

incineration.<br />

25<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> this Directive is to prevent or to limit as far as practicable negative<br />

effects on the environment, in particular pollution by emissions into air, soil,<br />

surface water and groundwater, and the resulting risks to human health, from<br />

the incineration and co-incineration <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

Co-incineration plant is defined under Article 3(5) as:<br />

stationary or mobile plant whose main purpose is the generation <strong>of</strong> energy or<br />

production <strong>of</strong> material products and:<br />

— which uses wastes as a regular or additional fuel; or<br />

— in which waste is thermally treated for the purpose <strong>of</strong> disposal.<br />

Hence, the Directive covers emissions from facilities such as cement kilns which may<br />

make use <strong>of</strong> wastes as fuel.<br />

The Directive does not apply to some plants, set out in Article 2, such as those<br />

treating only: 30<br />

(i) vegetable waste from agriculture and forestry,<br />

(ii) vegetable waste from the food processing industry, if the heat generated is<br />

recovered,<br />

(iii) fibrous vegetable waste from virgin pulp production and from production <strong>of</strong><br />

paper from pulp, if it is co-incinerated at the place <strong>of</strong> production and the heat<br />

generated is recovered,<br />

(iv) wood waste with the exception <strong>of</strong> wood waste which may contain<br />

halogenated organic compounds or heavy metals as a result <strong>of</strong> treatment with<br />

wood preservatives or coating, and which includes in particular such wood<br />

waste originating from construction and demolition waste,<br />

(v) cork waste.<br />

Such plants may be regulated differently to incineration plants covered by the<br />

Directive.<br />

Some key aspects <strong>of</strong> the Directive are highlighted below.<br />

Article 4 states: 31<br />

29 Directive 2000/76/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 4 December 2000 on the<br />

incineration <strong>of</strong> waste, Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Communities L 332/91, 28/12/2000.<br />

30 Directive 2000/76/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 4 December 2000 on the<br />

incineration <strong>of</strong> waste, Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Communities L 332/91, 28/12/2000.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


26<br />

29/09/09<br />

2. Without prejudice to Directive 96/61/EC, the application for a permit for an<br />

incineration or co-incineration plant to the competent authority shall include a<br />

description <strong>of</strong> the measures which are envisaged to guarantee that:<br />

(a) the plant is designed, equipped and will be operated in such a manner that<br />

the requirements <strong>of</strong> this Directive are taking into account the categories <strong>of</strong><br />

waste to be incinerated;<br />

(b) the heat generated during the incineration and co-incineration process is<br />

recovered as far as practicable e.g. through combined heat and power, the<br />

generating <strong>of</strong> process steam or district heating;<br />

(c) the residues will be minimised in their amount and harmfulness and<br />

recycled where appropriate;<br />

(d) the disposal <strong>of</strong> the residues which cannot be prevented, reduced or<br />

recycled will be carried out in conformity with national and Community<br />

legislation.<br />

3. The permit shall be granted only if the application shows that the proposed<br />

measurement techniques for emissions into the air comply with Annex III and,<br />

as regards water, comply with Annex III paragraphs 1 and 2.<br />

Article 6 lays down some <strong>of</strong> the key technical operating conditions for incineration<br />

and co-incineration plants. Article 7 sets out rules regarding emission limit values,<br />

making reference to Annex II and Annex V <strong>of</strong> the Directive, where these limit values<br />

are set out. Articles 8 and 9 refer to water discharges, and the management <strong>of</strong><br />

residues, respectively. Article 10 lays out the requirements for control and monitoring,<br />

whilst Article 11 establishes rules regarding measurement requirements, and<br />

essentially sets out what is required in order to demonstrate compliance with the limit<br />

values set out in the various Annexes to the Directive.<br />

It is <strong>of</strong> interest to note that the pre-amble to the Directive makes reference to the<br />

United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE) Convention on long-range<br />

transboundary air pollution with regard to emissions <strong>of</strong> dioxins and furans, and <strong>of</strong><br />

particulates and mercury.<br />

31 Directive 2000/76/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 4 December 2000 on the<br />

incineration <strong>of</strong> waste, Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Communities L 332/91, 28/12/2000.


1.7 The UNECE / Stockholm Conventions<br />

1.7.1 The 1979 UNECE Convention on Long-range Transboundary Air<br />

Pollution and Protocols:<br />

The 1979 UNECE Convention on Long-range Transboundary Air Pollution (CLRTAP)<br />

entered into force in 1983. It has since been extended by eight specific protocols. The<br />

two most relevant <strong>of</strong> protocols are those on POPs and Heavy Metals. 32<br />

POP POPs POP s Protocol: Protocol: The Executive body to the Convention on Long-Range Transboundary<br />

Air Pollution adopted the Protocol on Persistent Organic Pollutants (POPs) on 24th June 1998. The POPs protocol focuses on a list <strong>of</strong> 16 substances that have been<br />

selected according to agreed risk criteria. They comprise eleven pesticides, two<br />

industrial chemicals and, <strong>of</strong> particular interest for incineration, three unintentionally<br />

produced by-products.<br />

The Protocol was signed by 36 <strong>of</strong> 48 Parties to the CLRTAP and by all EU Member<br />

States and entered into force on 23 rd October 2003. Ireland signed the UNECE<br />

protocol on 24 th June 1998 but has not yet ratified. 33 The protocol has 29 Parties and<br />

entered into force on 23 rd October 2003. The Protocol was signed by the European<br />

Community on 24 th June 1998 and approved on 30 th April 2004.<br />

The objective <strong>of</strong> the protocol is to eliminate discharges, emissions and losses <strong>of</strong><br />

POPs. It bans the production and use <strong>of</strong> some chemicals outright (aldrin, chlordane,<br />

chlordecone, dieldrin, endrin, hexabromobiphenyl, mirex and toxaphene); others are<br />

scheduled for elimination at a later stage (DDT, heptachlor, hexachlorobenzene<br />

(HCB), and polychlorinated biphenyls (PCBs)). It includes provisions for dealing with<br />

the wastes <strong>of</strong> chemicals that will be banned.<br />

It also obliges Parties to reduce their emissions <strong>of</strong> dioxins, furans, polycyclic aromatic<br />

hydrocarbons (PAHs) and HCB below their levels in 1990 (or an alternative year<br />

between 1985 and 1995). For the incineration <strong>of</strong> municipal, hazardous and medical<br />

waste it lays down specific limit values.<br />

The The Protocol Protocol on on Heavy Heavy Metals Metals: Metals This was adopted on 24 June 1998 in Aarhus,<br />

Denmark. It targets three particularly harmful metals: cadmium, lead and mercury.<br />

According to one <strong>of</strong> the basic obligations, Parties have to reduce their emissions for<br />

these three metals below their levels in 1990 (or an alternative year between 1985<br />

and 1995). The Protocol aims to cut emissions from industrial sources (iron and steel<br />

industry, non-ferrous metal industry), combustion processes (power generation, road<br />

transport) and waste incineration.<br />

It lays down stringent limit values for emissions from stationary sources and suggests<br />

best available techniques (BAT) for these sources, such as appropriate filters or<br />

32 UNECE (1998) Aarhus Protocol to the 1979 Convention on Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution<br />

on Persistent Organic Pollutants. 1998; UNECE (1998) Aarhus Protocol to the 1979 Convention on<br />

Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution on Heavy Metal. 1998.<br />

33 http://www.unece.org/env/lrtap/status/98pop_st.htm<br />

27<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


scrubbers for combustion sources or mercury-free processes. It also introduces<br />

measures to lower heavy metal emissions from other products, such as mercury in<br />

batteries, and proposes the introduction <strong>of</strong> management measures for other mercurycontaining<br />

products, such as electrical components (thermostats, switches),<br />

measuring devices (thermometers, manometers, barometers), fluorescent lamps,<br />

dental amalgam, pesticides and paint.<br />

1.7.2 The Stockholm Convention<br />

The Stockholm Convention was formally adopted on 22 nd – 23 rd May 2001. 34 The<br />

Convention entered into force on 17 th May 2004, the ninetieth day after the date <strong>of</strong><br />

deposit <strong>of</strong> the fiftieth instrument <strong>of</strong> ratification. By 11 th May 2009 there were 152<br />

signatories and 163 countries and economic regions including the European<br />

Community were parties.<br />

The Convention establishes a strong international regime for promoting global action<br />

on twelve POPs which are also included in the UNECE Protocol. Specific reference is<br />

made to the precautionary approach as set out in Principle 15 <strong>of</strong> the Rio Declaration<br />

on Environment and Development. Nine intentionally produced chemicals (aldrin,<br />

chlordane, dieldrin, endrin, HCB, heptachlor, mirex, toxaphene and PCBs) are subject<br />

to a ban on production and use except where there are generic or specific<br />

exemptions. In addition, the production and use <strong>of</strong> DDT is severely restricted.<br />

There are special provisions for those Parties with regulatory assessment schemes to<br />

review existing chemicals for POPs characteristics and to take regulatory measures<br />

with the aim <strong>of</strong> preventing the development, production and marketing <strong>of</strong> new<br />

substances with POPs characteristics.<br />

At the fourth Conference <strong>of</strong> the Parties, held in Geneva between 4 th and 8 th May<br />

2009, nine new POPs were added to the Convention under the review procedures. 35<br />

These chemicals were:<br />

28<br />

� Alpha hexachlorocyclohexane to Annex A;<br />

� Beta hexachlorocyclohexane to Annex A;<br />

� Hexabromodiphenyl ether and heptabromodiphenyl ether to Annex A (the<br />

commercial formulation <strong>of</strong> Octa Brominated Diphenyl Ether ‘c Octa BDE’);<br />

� Tetrabromodiphenyl ether and pentabromodiphenyl ether to Annex A (the<br />

commercial formulation <strong>of</strong> Penta Brominated Diphenyl Ether ‘c Penta BDE’);;<br />

� Chlordecone to Annex A;<br />

� Hexabromobiphenyl to Annex A;<br />

34 UNEP (2001) Stockholm Convention on Persistent Organic Pollutants<br />

, United Nations Environment<br />

Programme, Editor. 2001.<br />

35 Stockholm Convention (2009) Governments Unite to Step-up Reduction on Global DDT Reliance and<br />

add Nine New Chemicals under <strong>International</strong> Treaty, Press Release, Geneva, 8 May 2009.<br />

29/09/09


29<br />

� Lindane to Annex A;<br />

� Pentachlorobenzene to Annex A and C; and<br />

� Perfluorooctane sulfonic acid, its salts and perfluorooctane sulfonyl fluoride to<br />

Annex B.<br />

Within Europe, this is likely to lead to a revision <strong>of</strong> Regulation 850/2004, and this will<br />

have knock-on implications for Ireland.<br />

The use <strong>of</strong> best available techniques for new sources within the major source<br />

categories, including incineration <strong>of</strong> municipal waste, is promoted and, in accordance<br />

with the implementation schedule <strong>of</strong> a country’s action plan, is required.<br />

The Convention also foresees identification and safe management <strong>of</strong> stockpiles<br />

containing or consisting <strong>of</strong> POPs; this can include incineration residues. <strong>Waste</strong><br />

containing, consisting <strong>of</strong>, or contaminated with, POPs should be disposed <strong>of</strong> in such a<br />

way that the POP content is destroyed or irreversibly transformed. Where this does<br />

not represent the environmentally preferable option or where the POP content is low,<br />

waste shall be otherwise disposed <strong>of</strong> in an environmentally sound manner. Disposal<br />

operations that may lead to the recovery or re-use <strong>of</strong> POPs are forbidden, a barrier to<br />

the re-use <strong>of</strong> incinerator air pollution control residues.<br />

It should be noted that at present, the ‘low POPs level’ is currently set at 15 parts per<br />

billion for dioxin by Reg 1195/2006. 36 This level is higher than the dioxin levels which<br />

are likely to be found in modern incinerator air pollution control residues but is likely<br />

to be reduced in the future to a lower threshold as the Regulation requires that the<br />

issue is revisited and parties at the Fourth Conference <strong>of</strong> the Parties (COP4) to the<br />

Stockholm Convention have expressed concern that the levels need to be reduced.<br />

1.8 Summary<br />

In respect <strong>of</strong> waste management, there are some increasingly strong markers<br />

provided in respect <strong>of</strong> policy development. The revised <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive<br />

gives greater emphasis than has been present hitherto to the priority position<br />

accorded to waste prevention. Also, the revised Directive suggests that policy would<br />

do well to take heed <strong>of</strong> the requirement to:<br />

� Develop objectives in line with the hierarchy outlined in Article 4 <strong>of</strong> the WFD,<br />

though with departures from this ranking made clear where the case, based<br />

on life-cycle thinking, justifies this;<br />

� Include a specific programme for waste prevention. A forward looking strategy<br />

would pre-empt the decoupling objective foreseen by the WFD. Ireland’s<br />

National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme is a foresightful development in this<br />

regard;<br />

36 European Commission (2006) Council Regulation (EC) No 1195/2006 <strong>of</strong> 18 July 2006 amending<br />

Annex IV to Regulation (EC) No 850/2004 <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council on persistent<br />

organic pollutants. Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Union, 2006: p. L217/1 - 217/3<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


30<br />

� Put in place means to ensure that targets for recycling <strong>of</strong> at least 50% from<br />

household waste and 70% from construction and demolition waste are met in<br />

the spirit <strong>of</strong> pre-empting the WFD objectives. Ireland is already meeting the<br />

50% target for household waste, narrowly defined; 37<br />

� Ensure that mechanisms are in place which lead to the separate collection <strong>of</strong><br />

glass, metals, paper and plastic (where appropriate), again pre-empting the<br />

WFD requirements;<br />

� Implement measures designed to lead to separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste;<br />

� Implement policies or mechanisms that encourage the use <strong>of</strong> products <strong>of</strong><br />

biowaste management;<br />

� Ensure that where incineration or co-incineration are employed, permits<br />

should not be issued unless the recovery <strong>of</strong> energy takes place ‘with a high<br />

level <strong>of</strong> energy efficiency’;<br />

� Apply the polluter pays principle; and<br />

� Give substance to the concept <strong>of</strong> resource efficiency;<br />

In addition, Regulation (EC) No. 850/2004 should be implemented as soon as<br />

possible within Ireland. Although a National Implementation Plan is in development,<br />

this is a rather late development. 38 Finally, the Landfill Directive targets, and indeed,<br />

some <strong>of</strong> the technical measures besides (for example, the requirement to pre-treat<br />

waste prior to landfilling) need to be addressed. With respect to the Landfill Directive<br />

targets, no measure is yet in place which cascades responsibility for meeting these<br />

targets down to the actors capable <strong>of</strong> delivering them. With regard to the pretreatment<br />

requirements, the EPA has recently acted to rectify the absence <strong>of</strong> any<br />

such measures, though exactly how this will unfold is as yet unclear. 39<br />

37 The exact interpretation <strong>of</strong> this is yet to be made clear by the European Commission, though the<br />

suggestion is that the target may be applied to the totality <strong>of</strong> waste included within a country’s chosen<br />

range <strong>of</strong> waste streams.<br />

38 European Commission (2004) Regulation (EC) No 850/2004 Of The European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Council <strong>of</strong> 29 April 2004 on persistent organic pollutants and amending Directive 79/117/EEC Note<br />

that whilst this was published in the Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Union L158 <strong>of</strong> 30th April 2004. A<br />

Corrigendum to the Regulation was subsequently published in the Official Journal L229/5 <strong>of</strong> 29th June<br />

2004. 2004, Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Union L 229/5.<br />

39 EPA (2009) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> - Pre-treatment and Residuals <strong>Management</strong>: An EPA Technical<br />

Guidance Document, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

29/09/09


2.0 <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

2.1 Introduction<br />

There are a range <strong>of</strong> different policy instruments which could be used to address the<br />

issues which arise in the context <strong>of</strong> waste management. Most countries resort to a<br />

mix <strong>of</strong>:<br />

31<br />

� Command and control instruments, which set standards that have to be met<br />

(e.g. compulsory targets for recycling), or limits (e.g. to emissions <strong>of</strong> pollutants)<br />

that cannot be exceeded. These might include:<br />

• Technology standards:<br />

for example, elaboration <strong>of</strong> best available techniques;<br />

• Product quality standards:<br />

for example, standards for different quality grades <strong>of</strong> compost;<br />

• Emissions standards or limit values:<br />

for example, the limit values set for emissions from incinerators under<br />

the <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration Directive; and<br />

• Performance targets:<br />

for example, local authority recycling targets.<br />

� Economic instruments, including: 40<br />

• User charges:<br />

for example, charges for the use <strong>of</strong> waste services. Note that the<br />

definition <strong>of</strong> ‘charges’ is not formalised, but that typically, a charge will<br />

be paid in exchange for a service, and the charge will vary with the level<br />

<strong>of</strong> service demanded / received;<br />

• Product charges:<br />

for example, charges applied to products that create pollution either<br />

through their manufacture, consumption or disposal (e.g. charges on<br />

batteries). In the waste arena, these are typically used to modify<br />

relative prices and / or to finance collection and treatment systems;<br />

• Taxes:<br />

Taxes differ from charges in that they are unrequited payments to the<br />

central government. The unrequited nature <strong>of</strong> these payments relates<br />

to the fact that they are paid irrespective <strong>of</strong> the level <strong>of</strong> service received<br />

from central government (for example, landfill taxes, product (e.g.<br />

plastic bag) taxes, etc.). Taxes are occasionally ear-marked for specific<br />

40 See, for example, OECD (1999) Economic Instruments for Pollution Control and Natural Resources<br />

<strong>Management</strong> in OECD Countries: A Survey, ENV/EPOC/GEEI(98)35/REV1/FINAL, October 1999.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


32<br />

29/09/09<br />

purposes (as with the revenues from the Irish taxes, which are<br />

channelled to an Environmental Fund). There has been much<br />

discussion in the literature regarding the wisdom, or otherwise, <strong>of</strong> this<br />

type <strong>of</strong> approach; 41<br />

• Tradable / transferable allowances, or credits:<br />

for example, the use <strong>of</strong> tradable allowances for landfilling, or tradable<br />

compliance credits for achieving packaging recovery targets, as used<br />

(in both cases) in the UK;<br />

• Deposit-refund schemes:<br />

These are most commonly used for beverages<br />

• Non-compliance fees:<br />

imposed under civil law on polluters who do not comply with<br />

environmental or natural resource management requirements and<br />

regulations. They can be proportional to selected variables such as<br />

damage due to non-compliance, pr<strong>of</strong>its linked to reduced (non-)<br />

compliance costs,<br />

• Performance bonds:<br />

polluters or users may be required to deposit revenue in the form <strong>of</strong> a<br />

bond so as to guarantee compliance with specified requirements. The<br />

fund (or part <strong>of</strong> it) is typically refunded once compliance is achieved;<br />

• Liability payments:<br />

these are payments made to ‘victims’ to compensate for damage<br />

caused by pollution activity. They can operate in the context <strong>of</strong> specific<br />

liability rules and compensation schemes, or the payments can be<br />

made from a fund financed by contributions from ‘potential polluters’<br />

(the best examples relate to oil-spills); and<br />

• Subsidies:<br />

Subsidies include any form <strong>of</strong> explicit financial assistance to polluters<br />

(grants, s<strong>of</strong>t loans, tax breaks, accelerated depreciation, etc.).<br />

� Voluntary / negotiated agreements, which constitute non-statutory measures<br />

undertaken by an industry sector, <strong>of</strong>ten at the behest <strong>of</strong> government (or its<br />

41 There is also a great deal <strong>of</strong> discussion, in the literature, regarding whether a tax applied in the<br />

environmental sphere is ‘really environmental’, or ‘just a revenue raiser’. This debate <strong>of</strong>ten centres on<br />

how the revenue being raised is to be used (will it be used for environmental purposes?). The view <strong>of</strong><br />

the OECD on the matter is quite clear: it is not the use <strong>of</strong> revenue which makes a tax ‘environmental or<br />

not’, rather it is the basis for the tax itself (is it something which pollutes, or otherwise causes<br />

environmental harm?). The logic is quite sound: the effect <strong>of</strong> the incentive conveyed by the tax itself in<br />

the market ought not to be affected by the motives <strong>of</strong> government. The only question, therefore, is<br />

whether ear-marking <strong>of</strong> revenues is a good idea or not, and under what conditions might it be so.


33<br />

agencies), and occasionally under the threat <strong>of</strong> the application <strong>of</strong> one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

above. The OECD differentiates between four types <strong>of</strong> initiative: 42<br />

• Unilateral commitments made by polluters / producers;<br />

• Private agreements between polluters and pollutees (essentially,<br />

victims);<br />

• Environmental agreements negotiated between industry and public<br />

authorities (or their agents);<br />

• Voluntary programmes developed by public authorities, to which<br />

individual firms are invited to participate.<br />

Whatever the configuration <strong>of</strong> policy, it is important to note three things:<br />

1) None <strong>of</strong> the policies act in isolation;<br />

2) The distinction between categories is far from clear cut. For example, tradable<br />

allowances operate in either ‘cap-and-trade’ form or ‘baseline-and-credit’ form. In<br />

either case, the economic incentive is established through the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the<br />

cap, or the required change from baseline. In other words, there is a regulatory<br />

(target) component to the instrument as well as a economic / market based<br />

incentive (in the form <strong>of</strong> trading); and<br />

3) Importantly, when new policies are introduced, they essentially alter the economic<br />

calculus confronting actors in the economy. The calculus in terms <strong>of</strong> the potential<br />

benefits associated with evasion / illegal behaviour essentially change.<br />

Consequently, incentive / target based instruments need to be supported by<br />

adequate enforcement mechanisms, preferably anticipating the nature <strong>of</strong> illegal,<br />

quasi-legal and evasive behaviour to ensure that perverse consequences are kept<br />

to a minimum. It is not surprising, therefore, that the list <strong>of</strong> economic instruments<br />

elaborated by the OECD includes a growing number related to compliance,<br />

enforcement and liability.<br />

2.2 What is the Right <strong>Policy</strong> Mix?<br />

Attempts to elicit ‘the best’ policy mix have tended to focus on theoretical<br />

considerations. In addition, the evaluations tend to be dominated, not without some<br />

reasonable justification, by economic concerns. In essence, it is generally accepted<br />

that, in perfect markets, a first best solution is to apply taxes on all externalities so<br />

that the market internalises, within market prices, the costs <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

damages. Three clear problems arise:<br />

a) From the economic perspective, markets are not all perfect (the problem <strong>of</strong><br />

market failure); 43<br />

42 OECD (2003) Voluntary Approaches for Environmental <strong>Policy</strong>: Effectiveness, Efficiency and Usage in<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> Mixes, Paris: OECD.<br />

43 The issue <strong>of</strong> market failure is frequently treated, in what one might call economic orthodoxy, as<br />

though it provides a framework for analysis accepted by all economists. This is not entirely true. From<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


34<br />

b) In respect <strong>of</strong> both the status <strong>of</strong> economic science, and the status <strong>of</strong> the<br />

natural sciences, quantifying the external damages associated with economic<br />

activity is not straightforward; and<br />

c) From the political perspective, nation states do not have the competence to<br />

impose taxes in other nation states. They do, and may (with reasoned<br />

justification, and as long as the measures do not place imports at a<br />

disadvantage) apply border taxes on imports, but in order to internalise all<br />

externalities associated with producing imports, the complexity <strong>of</strong> border tax<br />

adjustments would be considerable.<br />

For this (and other political) reasons, few cases exist <strong>of</strong> environmental taxes that have<br />

been set through direct reference to externalities, the best examples being the UK<br />

landfill tax (in its early days), the UK aggregates tax and the Danish packaging tax.<br />

Much <strong>of</strong> the public policy sphere, therefore, relates to implementation <strong>of</strong> second best<br />

solutions wherever the first best solution – taxing the cause <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

damage, or subsidising the generation <strong>of</strong> positive externalities - is not readily<br />

available. An excellent example is provided by the case <strong>of</strong> recycling. If all externalities<br />

<strong>of</strong> producing primary and secondary materials were internalised, then most analyses<br />

suggest that the environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling would manifest themselves<br />

through a considerable price differential in favour <strong>of</strong> secondary materials. In the<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> the ability to implement the first best solution, public policy has, by and<br />

large, sought to encourage recycling through means <strong>of</strong> second best instruments.<br />

However, it may do so (depending upon the detail <strong>of</strong> implementation) at the expense<br />

<strong>of</strong> the potential incentives for waste prevention that the first best solution – through<br />

making both primary and secondary materials more expensive (but by differing<br />

amounts) – would effectively generate. In other words, the second best solution tends<br />

to ‘grope towards’ the outcome that the first best solution might deliver.<br />

Notwithstanding the above, typically, ex ante evaluations <strong>of</strong> environmental policy<br />

favour those that work through the market mechanism. The reason for this hinges on<br />

the assumed – and usually, real – heterogeneous nature <strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

opportunities for abatement <strong>of</strong> pollution, or for environmental improvement.<br />

an institutional perspective, markets do not ‘fail’ so much as they deliver (though not in a deterministic<br />

manner) the outcomes which are commensurate with their (institutional) design. The institutions do not<br />

‘fail’ either, other than in the sense that they do not deliver the sort <strong>of</strong> market which the orthodox<br />

economist would like to see. Since economists have been concerned (in their pursuit <strong>of</strong> the Holy Grail<br />

<strong>of</strong> ‘market success’) primarily with the notion <strong>of</strong> efficiency, we must presume that what is being sought<br />

is institutional change commensurate with the attainment <strong>of</strong> this goal. But as Bromley (Daniel W.<br />

Bromley (1989) Economic Interests and Institutions: The Conceptual Foundations <strong>of</strong> Public <strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

Oxford: Basil Blackwell) has pointed out, the question <strong>of</strong> efficiency lacks any social and policy<br />

relevance without asking whether efficiency in and <strong>of</strong> itself is a relevant policy goal. To the extent that<br />

one asks this question at all, one immediately begins to transgress what for many economists is the<br />

cherished boundary between ‘positivist’ economics (in which no value judgements are made - Mirowski<br />

(Philip Mirowski (1989) More Heat Than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's<br />

Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) has traced this habit amongst economists to what<br />

he calls their ‘physics envy’) and what (from a normative as opposed to a realist position) is a<br />

normative discipline, that <strong>of</strong> policy making,<br />

29/09/09


Mechanisms which operate through the market can ensure that a given<br />

environmental outcome is achieved at the lowest cost to the economy, overall.<br />

A key issue remains the ‘strength <strong>of</strong> the instrument’ to be applied. As mentioned<br />

above, this ought to consider the marginal environmental damages, or benefits, and<br />

the marginal private costs, but the former are not straightforward to measure, and the<br />

latter are not especially well understood in advance <strong>of</strong> a measure’s implementation. 44<br />

External costs are tolerably well known for some air pollutants for which the<br />

epidemiological evidence is <strong>of</strong> high quality, but even here, there remain debates<br />

concerning methodology. The strength <strong>of</strong> any instrument, whether target or economic<br />

instrument, therefore tends to be set through the political process and by negotiation,<br />

influenced by studies that may be carried out in the context <strong>of</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> the<br />

instrument. Lobbying also occurs with the intention <strong>of</strong> influencing the design <strong>of</strong> the<br />

instrument.<br />

In essence, therefore, the theory <strong>of</strong> public policy has not been highly influential in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> policy design. That being the case, ex post assessment <strong>of</strong> policy has much to<br />

recommend it. This can highlight policies with significant potential for environmental<br />

improvement.<br />

However, ex post policy assessments <strong>of</strong> a high quality are very rare. There is a weak<br />

tradition <strong>of</strong> policy evaluation, and policies are rarely implemented with a view to<br />

understanding the effects <strong>of</strong> the policy and learning from it. This is certainly true <strong>of</strong><br />

Irish waste management policy, but it applies with some force, also, to other<br />

countries’ waste policies. Quality evaluations seek to understand the effects <strong>of</strong> policy<br />

against a plausible counterfactual (i.e. what would have happened in the absence <strong>of</strong><br />

the policy).<br />

2.3 Key <strong>Policy</strong> Issues in <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong> management problems such as littering, ‘overproduction’ <strong>of</strong> waste, and levels<br />

<strong>of</strong> recycling that are considered to be ‘too low’, can be explained, in economic terms,<br />

as resulting from incorrect price incentives. Economic theory suggests that if a waste<br />

management system is to be efficient, then participants, such as producers and<br />

consumers, should at each step, face prices that reflect the marginal social cost (that<br />

is the social cost arising from the production <strong>of</strong> one extra unit <strong>of</strong> waste).<br />

For many waste management systems, prices do not accurately reflect marginal<br />

social costs for three key reasons. The first is that waste management <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

generates uncompensated external costs that impact upon third parties. The second<br />

is that handling <strong>of</strong> waste is frequently subsidised by governments who pay a<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> the marginal private cost <strong>of</strong> waste management, though this appears<br />

not to be a strong influence in Ireland. The third is that the pricing used to charge for<br />

44 The main reason for this is that the world is not static. Most ex post assessments are shy <strong>of</strong><br />

estimating how learning effects, innovation and technical change might have affected costs.<br />

Consequently, private costs tend to be over-estimated in ex ante policy assessments. In the case <strong>of</strong><br />

Irish waste management, this matter is compounded massively by the absence <strong>of</strong> a solid foundation<br />

from which to launch a meaningful analysis <strong>of</strong> the costs as they currently stand.<br />

35<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


waste management services is not always such that marginal changes in quantities<br />

are reflected in changes in the charges paid.<br />

The marginal private cost <strong>of</strong> waste management is composed <strong>of</strong> the extra wage and<br />

equipment costs, along with the opportunity cost <strong>of</strong> the land needed for collection<br />

and disposal <strong>of</strong> one extra unit <strong>of</strong> waste, all <strong>of</strong> which can readily be calculated.<br />

Marginal external costs, however, such as noise, dust, litter, and groundwater<br />

pollution are less obvious. The marginal social cost is simply the sum <strong>of</strong> marginal<br />

private costs and marginal external costs.<br />

Where external costs are present, marginal social costs (MSC) exceed marginal<br />

private costs (MPC). Where subsidies exist, MPC exceeds the price (P) paid by the<br />

waste generator, e.g. the household. In theory, creating an efficient system <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management requires the development <strong>of</strong> policies, such as taxation to internalise<br />

environmental costs, in order that the MPC equals the MSC, as well as the removal <strong>of</strong><br />

subsidies such that MPC equals P.<br />

2.3.1 Policies to Achieve the Optimal Pricing for <strong>Waste</strong> Services<br />

Numerous studies have considered what an optimal policy for municipal waste<br />

management might be. 45 As suggested above, the goal <strong>of</strong> such a policy would be to<br />

make manufacturers and consumers aware <strong>of</strong> the social costs associated with the<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> products, by introducing taxes that reflect the marginal social costs that<br />

products and packaging impose at the end <strong>of</strong> their use. This is not always possible in<br />

the direct sense where goods and services are widely traded, and where the ability <strong>of</strong><br />

national policy to influence matters is limited. It is possible with some <strong>of</strong> the impacts<br />

which occur within national borders, for example, with respect to disposal.<br />

Generally the most favoured approach <strong>of</strong> most theorists is one or other combination<br />

<strong>of</strong> an advanced disposal fee (ADF) levied on the manufacturer at the point <strong>of</strong> sale, a<br />

charge on householders for disposal (pay by use) (PBUC), and a subsidy for recycling<br />

or appropriate disposal. Palmer and Walls also consider an upstream combination<br />

tax/subsidy, where effectively the ADF is replaced by a tax on materials use and the<br />

subsidy is paid to collectors <strong>of</strong> recyclables. 46<br />

For a system with no recycling, theory suggests that the results from approaches<br />

based on either an ADF or PBUC, reflecting the marginal social costs <strong>of</strong> disposal, are<br />

45 See, for example, H. Bartelings (2003) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Problems, An Applied<br />

General Equilibrium Analysis, PhD Thesis, University <strong>of</strong> Wageningen; V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, P. Kooreman, M.<br />

Allers and D. Wiersma (2001) Weight-based Pricing in the Collection <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong>: The<br />

Oostzaan Case, Resource and Energy Economics, 23, pp.359-71; Thomas Skinner and Don Fullerton<br />

(1999), The Economics <strong>of</strong> Residential Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, NBER Working Paper 7326<br />

http://www.nber.org/papers/w7326; K. Palmer and M. Walls (1999) Extended Product Responsibility:<br />

An Economic Assessment <strong>of</strong> Alternative Policies, Discussion Paper 99-12, January 1999, Washington<br />

DC: Resources for the Future; Don Fullerton and Amy Raub (2003) Economic Analysis <strong>of</strong> Solid <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Policies, in OECD (2004) Addressing the Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, Paris: OECD.<br />

46 K. Palmer and M. Walls (1999) Extended Product Responsibility: An Economic Assessment <strong>of</strong><br />

Alternative Policies, Discussion Paper 99-12, January 1999, Washington DC: Resources for the Future.<br />

36<br />

29/09/09


identical, but in practice they have quite different characteristics and shortcomings.<br />

Two key differences are outlined below:<br />

37<br />

• Collection and disposal costs vary so it would be very difficult to design an ADF<br />

for producers, who may serve a national market, based on where the product<br />

is likely to be disposed to take account <strong>of</strong> the varying social costs <strong>of</strong> disposal.<br />

An PBUC on households, however, can take these more location and<br />

household specific aspects into account; and<br />

• Different products have varying collection and disposal costs. An ADF can vary<br />

according to the (typical) cost <strong>of</strong> collecting and disposing <strong>of</strong> the product, but an<br />

PBUC must be uniform across products (for example at a set price per tonne),<br />

unless it is to become very complicated and expensive to administer.<br />

Once recycling becomes an option, in theory, a subsidy to encourage recycling can be<br />

coupled with an ADF to encourage generation <strong>of</strong> the optimum level <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

However, the difficulties <strong>of</strong> transferring these theoretical approaches to the real world<br />

are neatly summarised by Porter: 47<br />

“Any ADF would ideally be equal to some aij where i is the product (or package)<br />

and j the place where it is sold (or more precisely, where it will be disposed <strong>of</strong>).<br />

But in fact, it would be very difficult to vary the ADF by place, so it would end<br />

up being ai, varying across products (and packages) but not across places.<br />

Similarly any trash collection charge (t) or recycling collection charge/refund<br />

(r) would ideally be equal to some tij or rij also varying across product and<br />

place. But in fact it is very difficult to vary them across products since that<br />

would require extensive household sorting or lengthy collector examinations,<br />

so these would end up being tj and rj varying across places but not across<br />

products. In a sentence, it is in practice impossible to achieve a fully first-best<br />

policy – close is as close as we can come”.<br />

In the absence <strong>of</strong> a perfect application <strong>of</strong> marginal cost pricing in the real world, an<br />

increasingly common approach is to attempt to internalise external costs through<br />

what is known as extended producer responsibility.<br />

2.3.2 Extended Producer Responsibility<br />

Extended producer responsibility (EPR) describes a range <strong>of</strong> approaches that aim to<br />

address the externalities associated with waste disposal through placing with<br />

producers the financial or physical responsibility for the environmental impacts their<br />

products have when their useful life ends. The goals <strong>of</strong> EPR in broad terms are both<br />

to relieve some <strong>of</strong> the financial burdens <strong>of</strong> waste management from municipalities,<br />

and to incentivise producers to reduce resources, increase use <strong>of</strong> secondary<br />

materials, and bring about waste reduction through product re-design. 48<br />

47 Richard C. Porter (2004), Efficient Targeting <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Policies in the Product Chain, in OECD (2004)<br />

Addressing the Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, Paris: OECD.<br />

48 OECD (2001) Extended Producer Responsibility: A Guidance Manual for Governments, Paris: OECD.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Several policy instruments are available that are aligned with the principles <strong>of</strong> EPR.<br />

These include advance disposal fees, deposit refunds, product take-back and<br />

recycled content standards. In accordance with Walls’ maxim that ‘the goal <strong>of</strong> EPR<br />

policy should be …… to maximize social welfare’, these instruments can be used to<br />

tackle negative externalities in an efficient manner. 49<br />

Results from a number <strong>of</strong> theoretical economic studies have shown that using an EPR<br />

instrument, namely a deposit-refund, can deliver reductions in waste more costeffectively<br />

than when other instruments are applied in isolation. 50 The key reason for<br />

this is the bringing together <strong>of</strong> output reduction and input substitution incentives<br />

within one policy. In cases where illegal dumping is considered a problem, or where<br />

recycling markets are not functioning well, EPR policies are considered to be<br />

particularly effective in creating appropriate incentives for reducing waste. 51<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> the key policy instruments, and variants <strong>of</strong> those instruments, that fall<br />

under the EPR umbrella, as detailed by Walls, are summarised below: 52<br />

38<br />

� Product take-back mandate and recycling rate target – Here the government<br />

requires manufacturers and/or retailers to accept the return <strong>of</strong> products once<br />

their useful life has ended. Such mandates are <strong>of</strong>ten combined with a<br />

recycling or waste diversion target requiring each producer to meet a recycling<br />

rate goal <strong>of</strong>, for example, 75% for its products. The German packaging law<br />

works in this way; take-back is required and material-specific recycling rate<br />

targets are set. Firms <strong>of</strong>ten form a ‘producer responsibility organisation’ (PRO)<br />

to handle collection, arrange for recycling, and ensure recycling targets are<br />

met in a cost-effective manner;<br />

29/09/09<br />

However, beyond increasing take-back and recycling rates, it is not always<br />

clear that such schemes actually impose a sufficient incentive on producers to<br />

both reduce packaging, and design more recyclable products.<br />

Fullerton and Raub 53 suggest that if the firm is only responsible for the private<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> disposal, it does not internalise the full social marginal cost. They argue<br />

49 M. Walls (2004) EPR <strong>Policy</strong> Goals and <strong>Policy</strong> Choices: What Does Economics Tell Us? In OECD<br />

(2004) Economic Aspects <strong>of</strong> Producer Responsibility, Paris: OECD.<br />

50 D. Fullerton and T. C. Kinnemann (1995), Garbage Recycling and Illicit Burning or Dumping, Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Environmental Economics and <strong>Management</strong>, 29 (1); T. Dinan (1993) Economic Efficiency Effects <strong>of</strong><br />

Alternative Policies for Reducing <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal, Journal <strong>of</strong> Environmental Economics and<br />

<strong>Management</strong> 25: 242–56; K. Palmer & M. Walls (1994) Materials Use and Solid <strong>Waste</strong>: An Evaluation<br />

<strong>of</strong> Policies, Resources for the Future Discussion Paper 95-02, Washington: Resources for the Future.<br />

51 M. Walls (2003) The Role <strong>of</strong> Economics in Extended Producer Responsibility: Making <strong>Policy</strong> Choices<br />

and Setting <strong>Policy</strong> Goals, Resources for the Future Discussion Paper 03-11, Washington: Resources for<br />

the Future.<br />

52 M. Walls (2006) Extended Producer Responsibility and Product Design: Economic Theory and<br />

Selected Case Studies, Resources for the Future Discussion Paper 06-08, Washington: Resources for<br />

the Future.<br />

53 D. Fullerton and A. Raub (2004) Economic Analysis <strong>of</strong> Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Policies, in OECD<br />

(2004) Addressing the Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, Paris: OECD


39<br />

that firms may still need to be made to pay the full marginal external damages<br />

<strong>of</strong> disposal, and that if this cost is internalised, they will then have the correct<br />

incentives, with no need for subsidies for ‘green design’ <strong>of</strong> products and<br />

packaging.<br />

OECD 54 identifies a range <strong>of</strong> external costs and benefits associated with<br />

different waste management options. While landfilling has a negative benefit<br />

(i.e. a cost) ranging from -€9.61 to -€44.75 per tonne, recycling <strong>of</strong> paper/card<br />

has an external benefit <strong>of</strong> €45.86 to €94.17 per tonne. Thus a tonne <strong>of</strong><br />

paper/card that is recycled rather than being landfilled has an external benefit<br />

ranging from around €55 per tonne to €138 per tonne.<br />

Indeed in many cases it is clear that producers involved in such schemes still<br />

do not pay the full marginal private cost <strong>of</strong> disposal, let alone the full marginal<br />

social cost. Current levels <strong>of</strong> payments from producers to PROs <strong>of</strong>ten simply<br />

cover a typical cost <strong>of</strong> collecting and transporting material to a recycler, thus<br />

not meeting other private costs <strong>of</strong> landfill such as gate fees. Basing fees on<br />

marginal social costs <strong>of</strong> disposal would allow for a greater incentive for the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> products for recycling, with subsequent higher payment for<br />

collectors more accurately reflecting the benefits <strong>of</strong> avoiding disposal via<br />

landfill.<br />

On a wider scale, where municipalities still undertake the collection <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging materials for recycling in countries where producer responsibility<br />

schemes operate, the private costs have certainly not been fully internalised 55.<br />

� Product take-back mandate and recycling rate targets with a tradable recycling<br />

credit scheme – The same as outlined above except that targets apply not to<br />

each individual producer but to the industry as a whole; tradable credits are<br />

issued with firms trading among themselves. An industry wide recycling rate<br />

target can therefore be met with some producers exceeding the target and<br />

some failing to meet it. Tradable credit schemes can be set up in various ways.<br />

One example is the UK’s packaging recovery system. Reprocessors <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging materials issue “packaging waste recovery notes”, or PRNs, which<br />

firms and PROs can trade with one another to meet their recycling obligations;<br />

� Voluntary product take-back with recycling rate targets – In such an approach,<br />

firms within an industry agree to organise a take-back system for their<br />

products and set recycling goals. There are no government regulations or laws<br />

mandating compliance, and no penalties for not meeting the goals. In the US,<br />

voluntary take-back programs <strong>of</strong> this type include the Rechargeable Battery<br />

Recycling Corporation (RBRC), which represents manufacturers <strong>of</strong><br />

rechargeable batteries, who pay a fee to operate a collection and recycling<br />

54 D. Hogg (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges,<br />

ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD.<br />

55 Perchards (2005) Study on the Progress <strong>of</strong> the Implementation and Impact <strong>of</strong> Directive 94/62/EC<br />

on the Functioning <strong>of</strong> the Internal Market, Final Report; Eunomia et al (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report for Defra, May 2007<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


40<br />

29/09/09<br />

system. Another is Carpet America Recovery Effort (CARE), created by an<br />

agreement that arose from a 2002 MOU between manufacturers, several<br />

state governments and the US EPA. The memorandum set voluntary recycling<br />

rate goals for carpet to be reached by 2012;<br />

� Advance recycling fees – An ARF – which was originally referred to as an<br />

advance disposal fee, or ADF – is a tax assessed on product sales and <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

used to cover the cost <strong>of</strong> recycling. ARFs are <strong>of</strong>ten assessed per unit <strong>of</strong> the<br />

product sold but can also be assessed on the basis <strong>of</strong> weight. ARFs may be<br />

visible to the consumer on the purchase <strong>of</strong> a product, as a separate line on the<br />

bill, or imposed upstream on producers and later incorporated in the sales<br />

price; and<br />

� ARF combined with a recycling subsidy – An ARF raises money that can be<br />

used in a variety <strong>of</strong> ways. The incentive effects <strong>of</strong> the policy depend greatly on<br />

both the type <strong>of</strong> ARF and the use <strong>of</strong> revenues. A ‘back-end’ recycling subsidy –<br />

either a subsidy per unit <strong>of</strong> the product recycled or unit weight <strong>of</strong> material<br />

recycled – leads to quite a different policy instrument than one in which ARF<br />

revenues are used to cover waste management cost or infrastructure costs in<br />

a lump-sum fashion. California’s used oil programme, the western Canada<br />

used oil programme, lead-acid batter programmes in several US states, and<br />

California’s e-waste programme are all ARF/recycling subsidy programs.<br />

All <strong>of</strong> these policy instruments make the producer financially or physically responsible<br />

for the end-<strong>of</strong>-life environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> his product. In this sense, they could all<br />

be considered EPR. However, they have very different incentive effects and ultimately<br />

may lead to different environmental outcomes, and the costs <strong>of</strong> the instrument may<br />

differ widely.<br />

Other non-EPR policy instruments can lead to similar outcomes but do not focus<br />

upstream on producers. To illustrate the contrast, four such non-EPR instruments are<br />

outlined below<br />

� Landfill bans – Many US states and European countries ban disposal <strong>of</strong><br />

particular items in landfills (or incinerators);<br />

� ‘Pay as you throw’ pricing <strong>of</strong> waste collection/disposal – A large number <strong>of</strong><br />

Irish authorities, as well as many municipalities in the EU, more than 4,000<br />

communities in the US, all municipalities in South Korea and many other<br />

municipalities in other countries besides, charge for the collection and<br />

management <strong>of</strong> waste using a variable fee element. In some countries, end-<strong>of</strong>life<br />

fees are charged for specific items that are difficult to dispose <strong>of</strong>. None <strong>of</strong><br />

these policies are aimed at the producer, and so do not qualify as EPR, but<br />

they do have some effects on waste generation and recycling, usually through<br />

affecting consumption decisions and through changing citizens’ behaviour.<br />

� Recycling subsidies – The government may raise funds in ways that are not<br />

ARFs/ADFs, and subsidize recycling. The government could make a payment<br />

per unit or kg <strong>of</strong> material recycled, or it could make lump-sum grants to<br />

communities or recycling centres. Such grants are quite common in the US.<br />

Whether the subsidy is per unit volume, per unit <strong>of</strong> weight, or a one time lump<br />

sum will have different effects; and


41<br />

� Recycling investment tax credits – In this case, government gives a credit on<br />

income taxes to anyone who invests in recycling infrastructure. Effectively this<br />

is a direct subsidy to capital.<br />

2.4 Summary<br />

The above discussion focuses on some <strong>of</strong> the key issues confronting policy makers<br />

who might seek to implement a policy that is ‘optimal’ from the economic perspective.<br />

There are considerable problems with seeking to design such a policy configuration,<br />

many <strong>of</strong> which have been touched upon above.<br />

In essence, however, the suggestion is that the workings <strong>of</strong> the market can be<br />

harnessed to deliver environmental benefits. Some lessons are the standard ones:<br />

ins<strong>of</strong>ar as possible, markets should be made to operate more efficiently by<br />

internalising externalities. However, here, first best solutions, particularly where the<br />

matter <strong>of</strong> waste prevention are concerned, are not so obviously available owing to the<br />

information needs, and the absence <strong>of</strong> any clear hope, at least for the foreseeable<br />

future, <strong>of</strong> multilateral externality taxes (which, in any case, would be fiendishly difficult<br />

to design such that they were genuinely reflecting externalities).<br />

The issue <strong>of</strong> policy design is a complex one. In Walls’ words: 56<br />

Identifying, designing, and implementing cost-effective environmental policies<br />

is no small job. Accomplishing this goal when multiple environmental<br />

objectives are on the table, when it is vital that the policy spur DfE [design for<br />

the environment], and when some markets, such as recycling markets,<br />

function poorly is even more difficult.<br />

This is the challenge which faces the existing study – to focus on the relevant<br />

objectives, and the necessary policies required to deliver these.<br />

56 M. Walls (2004) EPR <strong>Policy</strong> Goals and <strong>Policy</strong> Choices: What Does Economics Tell Us? In OECD<br />

(2004) Economic Aspects <strong>of</strong> Producer Responsibility, Paris: OECD.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


KEY INSTITUTIONAL ISSUES<br />

Ireland has been moving from a government run monopoly <strong>of</strong> waste management<br />

services in the 1990s toward a privatised approach to waste collection and disposal.<br />

Forfás (2008) estimates that 67 percent <strong>of</strong> municipal waste in Irish regions is<br />

collected by private companies. 57<br />

Ireland has a set up <strong>of</strong> 29 local authorities and 5 urban authorities. These have been<br />

consolidated into regions for the management <strong>of</strong> waste, giving rise to 7 regions and 3<br />

independent local authorities. The regions are responsible for designing waste<br />

management plans in line with the national waste management plan devised by<br />

central government.<br />

In 2006 dissatisfaction in the waste industry led to a government decision to review<br />

waste regulations. This was welcomed by IBEC 58 who had outlined several issues<br />

pertaining to Irish waste management for several previous years.<br />

A review <strong>of</strong> regulations was required, according to IBEC, for the following reasons:<br />

42<br />

� Artificially high cost <strong>of</strong> waste management in Ireland (as a result <strong>of</strong> an<br />

imperfect market);<br />

57 Forfás, (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Benchmarking Analysis and <strong>Policy</strong> Priorities, available at:<br />

http://www.forfas.ie/media/forfas080528_waste_benchmarking.pdf<br />

58 IBEC (2006) Press Centre: IBEC welcomes Governments review <strong>of</strong> waste market, available at:<br />

http://www.ibec.ie/ibec/press/presspublicationsdoclib3.nsf/wvPCICCC/2DE72CDC52A50B9780257<br />

1BF0057ADA5?OpenDocument<br />

29/09/09


43<br />

� Lack <strong>of</strong> communication between the regions;<br />

� Conflict <strong>of</strong> interest with respect to local authorities; and<br />

� Inadequate development <strong>of</strong> infrastructure.<br />

This report builds on an earlier report for Greenstar carried out by Eunomia in 2007 59.<br />

The previous report identified several key institutional issues within the Irish waste<br />

management industry. The following analysis will target each <strong>of</strong> three issues and<br />

examine both the causes <strong>of</strong> and potential solutions.<br />

The issues for consideration are:<br />

1) Competition ‘in the Market’, or ‘for the Market’;<br />

2) Governance structures / responsibilities for delivery <strong>of</strong> national strategy; and<br />

3) The role <strong>of</strong> local authorities (characterised by some as being regulator and player<br />

in the market).<br />

59 Eunomia, with TOBIN (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Planning and Regulation in Ireland, Final Report for<br />

Greenstar.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


3.0 Competition in the Market for <strong>Waste</strong> Collection<br />

Some Irish local authorities moved away from providing household waste<br />

management services in the mid 1990’s following the introduction <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Act 1996. The market for waste services then opened for competition<br />

with the local authorities effectively determining who could compete in the collection<br />

market (and through providing which service) through their role in issuing waste<br />

collection permits. The OECD discusses the appropriate approach to competition. 60 It<br />

suggests there are two categories <strong>of</strong> competition which could be considered in the<br />

context <strong>of</strong> the Irish market:<br />

44<br />

1) Competition in the market; and<br />

2) Competition for the market.<br />

3.1 Definitions<br />

3.1.1 Competition in the Market<br />

This can be viewed as a standard free market approach to service provision. The ideal<br />

free market approach consists <strong>of</strong> removing all trade barriers thus letting the market<br />

and competitors within the market adjust to the equilibrium, or most efficient, level <strong>of</strong><br />

participation. To develop the aims <strong>of</strong> central government regarding waste, a certain<br />

level <strong>of</strong> regulation will exist in the market. Householders choose to contract<br />

individually with a waste collection company (or not, as the case may be).<br />

There has been, in the context <strong>of</strong> the existing situation in Ireland some discussion as<br />

to the need, or otherwise, for a regulator in the market. 61<br />

3.1.2 Competition for the Market<br />

This relates to competition for a contract to be responsible for waste management for<br />

a specific geographic region. This occurs through periodic tendering processes, in<br />

which companies bid for time-limited monopolies over service provision. Through the<br />

tendering process, costs <strong>of</strong> the underlying service are revealed. Key to obtaining value<br />

for money is the design <strong>of</strong> the tendering process itself. There is a considerable body<br />

<strong>of</strong> literature regarding the economics <strong>of</strong> contracts, and the likely behaviour <strong>of</strong><br />

participants in bidding situations. 62 In practice, there is also a variety <strong>of</strong> experience<br />

with tendering processes.<br />

60 OECD (2000) Competition in Local Services: Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, DAFFE/CLP(2000)13<br />

61 DoEHLG (2006) Regulation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Sector: Consultation Paper,<br />

http://www.environ.ie/en/Publications/Environment/<strong>Waste</strong>/<strong>Waste</strong><strong>Management</strong>/FileDownLoad,1446,<br />

en.pdf<br />

62 See, for example, J-J. Lafont (1989) The Economics <strong>of</strong> Uncertainty and Information, Cambridge: MIT<br />

Press; J-J. Lafont and J. Tirole (1993) A Theory <strong>of</strong> Incentives in Procurement and Regulation,<br />

29/09/09


3.2 Issues with Current Situation<br />

In the waste industry competition in the market can provide a benefit to customers<br />

through revealing an efficient price and, where the process is well managed, through<br />

bringing forth a choice <strong>of</strong> services, some <strong>of</strong> which might include innovative aspects.<br />

The OECD proposes that for large producers <strong>of</strong> waste, competition in the market<br />

approach is possible and appropriate. 63 This is particularly true <strong>of</strong> major commercial<br />

waste producers and producers <strong>of</strong> industrial waste.<br />

For other producers <strong>of</strong> (smaller quantities <strong>of</strong>) waste, however, the issues that can<br />

arise from an ‘in’ the market approach to competition in waste management service<br />

provision are as follows:<br />

45<br />

� The absence <strong>of</strong> service provision in some areas where the marginal costs <strong>of</strong><br />

provision are high relative to the likelihood <strong>of</strong> gaining full cost recovery. This is<br />

sometimes referred to as ‘cherry picking’ by private companies <strong>of</strong> customers,<br />

but the reality is more that anything other than ‘cherries’ is avoided<br />

completely; 64<br />

� Lowered level <strong>of</strong> service quality due to the desire to reduce the costs <strong>of</strong> service<br />

provision;<br />

� Reduced likelihood <strong>of</strong> the scope <strong>of</strong> the service being broadened to include<br />

separate collection <strong>of</strong> new materials due to the risks inherent in<br />

understanding the likely level <strong>of</strong> service uptake (and hence, the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

provision);<br />

� An increase in illegal activity related to the level <strong>of</strong> coverage. The counterpart<br />

<strong>of</strong> the ‘cherry-picking’ issue is that service coverage is less than 100%.<br />

Currently the EPA estimates that service coverage stood at 80% in 2007. 65<br />

One European survey noted: 66<br />

‘when looking at the quantity <strong>of</strong> MSW that is collected regularly in<br />

different countries, nearly half <strong>of</strong> the 24 countries that responded on<br />

this issue - Austria, Andorra, Belgium, Germany, Liechtenstein,<br />

Cambridge: MIT Press; Bernard Salanie (1997) The Economics <strong>of</strong> Contracts: A Primer, Cambridge: MIT<br />

Press.<br />

63 OECD (2000) Competition in Local Services: Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, DAFFE/CLP(2000)13<br />

64 ‘Cherry picking’ refers to the selection <strong>of</strong> the best, or most lucrative, customers or householders. The<br />

consultation on waste carried out by the DoEHLG notes that this is an issue with any utility that<br />

becomes privatised (which is effectively what has occurred in the Irish market). DoEHLG, 2006,<br />

‘Regulation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Sector’, available at:<br />

http://www.environ.ie/en/Publications/Environment/<strong>Waste</strong>/<strong>Waste</strong><strong>Management</strong>/FileDownLoad,1446,<br />

en.pdf<br />

65 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Wexford: EPA.<br />

66 C. Preda (2007) MSW <strong>Management</strong> in Europe, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> World, July 20007,<br />

http://www.waste-management-world.com/display_article/304406/123/CRTIS/none/none/MSWmanagement-in-Europe/<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


46<br />

29/09/09<br />

Lithuania, Luxembourg, Monaco, Switzerland and the UK - estimate<br />

100% MSW collection rates. The remaining countries, which by and<br />

large are from Eastern and South-eastern Europe, reported collection<br />

grades below 100%.<br />

The Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland and Slovenia report collection<br />

rates <strong>of</strong> >95%; Azerbaijan, Estonia, Greece, Hungary and Sweden 90-<br />

95%; Bulgaria, Romania and Poland 80-85%; and Ireland 77%. The<br />

reported minimum was 50% for Montenegro.<br />

Where no service exists, or where it is provided, but only at very high cost,<br />

those who are not covered have to make ‘alternative arrangements’ for their<br />

waste. In some cases, this is likely to encourage the management <strong>of</strong> waste in<br />

ways that are illegal (dumping), or unsociable (burning). 67 At the same time,<br />

because there is no obvious correspondence between the charges at civic<br />

amenity sites and charges requested <strong>of</strong> households, households could<br />

conceivably deposit waste at civic amenity sites for lower charges;<br />

� Failure to capitalise on economies <strong>of</strong> density in terms <strong>of</strong> logistics. The OECD<br />

notes that the scope for competition in the market relies on the economies <strong>of</strong><br />

density – the more dense the area the more likely that competition in the<br />

market will be a successful system; 68 and<br />

� Enhanced uncertainty on the part <strong>of</strong> developers <strong>of</strong> treatment facilities, as to<br />

whether the facility will be commercially bankable (because <strong>of</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong><br />

security regarding the supply <strong>of</strong> waste into the facility).<br />

The above issues would tend to arise even where the market is a competitive one.<br />

They may be exacerbated where the market is not competitive because only one<br />

service provider exists, or where one is dominant in a given area. In this context, it is<br />

worth considering the potential <strong>of</strong> the dominance <strong>of</strong> a given provider to act as a<br />

barrier to entry to other firms, even in a market where capital requirements for<br />

starting up waste collection enterprises are smaller than in many other industries.<br />

The mere fact that a provider already exists implies that it is in a better position to<br />

benefit from economies <strong>of</strong> density, with would-be competitors being unlikely to<br />

achieve the same densities as the incumbent provider in the short-term. To attract<br />

customers, therefore, the service provider would most likely have to seek to attract<br />

customers at price levels below the cost <strong>of</strong> delivery, at least in the short-term. This<br />

issue was raised in the context <strong>of</strong> a ruling by The Competition Authority: 69<br />

67 It is not clear that backyard burning <strong>of</strong> waste is against the law. See, for example, Sue Scott and<br />

Dorothy Watson (2006) Introduction <strong>of</strong> Weight-Based Charges for Domestic Solid <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal, Final<br />

Report Prepared for the EPA by the Economic and Social Research Institute, (2000-DS-6-M1).<br />

68 OECD (2000) Competition in Local Services: Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, DAFFE/CLP(2000)13<br />

69 The Competition Authority (2005) Decision <strong>of</strong> The Competition Authority (Case COM/108/02)<br />

concerning Alleged Excessive Pricing by Greenstar Holdings in the Provision <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Collection Services in Northeast Wicklow, 30 th August 2005, available at:<br />

http://tca.ie/search.aspx?SearchTerm=e/05/002


47<br />

Greenstar claims that when the local authorities first left the waste collection<br />

business, private operators cornered territories and it is now very difficult to<br />

enter another operator’s high density area. Unless a firm goes into its rival’s<br />

high density area very aggressively it is unlikely to succeed. One operator<br />

interviewed confirmed that in order to compete with Greenstar in northeast<br />

Wicklow they would probably have to go in below cost to try and secure a<br />

sufficient customer base. Another operator noted Greenstar’s customer<br />

density as a factor affecting its decision not to enter that market and the fact<br />

that Greenstar has sufficient resources at its disposal to respond to attempts<br />

to compete with it by directing additional resources to the area in question.<br />

Greenstar overcame the difficulties associated with entering other operators’<br />

high density areas in the northeast Wicklow market by entering via acquisition<br />

in 2000 and acquiring the incumbent operators’ existing customer bases.<br />

However, any new entrants in the relevant market will now have to secure a<br />

customer base via the greenfield route, the difficulties with which are<br />

described above.<br />

In addition, the commercial reality <strong>of</strong> the Irish household waste collection<br />

market is that collectors generally appear unwilling to enter each other’s<br />

areas <strong>of</strong> operation or to compete head-to-head with each other, although<br />

competition may occur at the boundary between the areas served by each<br />

firm. One operator contacted as part <strong>of</strong> a previous enquiry by The Competition<br />

Authority claimed that household waste collection has naturally evolved in<br />

such a way that each <strong>of</strong> the operators tends to have control over certain areas<br />

but that some overlap occurs on the outskirts <strong>of</strong> their areas <strong>of</strong> operation. The<br />

Competition Authority’s previous market enquiries have shown that even<br />

where there are three or more private operators servicing a particular county<br />

in the State, this does not automatically imply that these operators compete<br />

head-to-head within that county. Often these firms have control over<br />

household waste collection in a certain part <strong>of</strong> that county and compete only<br />

on the boundaries <strong>of</strong> their areas <strong>of</strong> operation. Even in some boundary areas<br />

where household waste collectors operate side-by-side The Competition<br />

Authority has received complaints regarding a general unwillingness among<br />

collectors to infringe on each other’s territory and a general preference to<br />

focus on retaining their existing customers without trying to expand into their<br />

competitors’ terrain.<br />

While this general business model may help explain the lack <strong>of</strong> new entry into<br />

the northeast Wicklow household waste collection market since 2000, it is<br />

unlikely in itself to constitute significant evidence <strong>of</strong> entry barriers as it is more<br />

a choice or preference <strong>of</strong> the individual firm rather than a rigid structural<br />

feature <strong>of</strong> the market concerned. It is nonetheless consistent with the finding<br />

that an incumbent firm enjoys substantial cost advantages in terms <strong>of</strong> its<br />

existing customer density and can consequently react strongly to any new<br />

entry into its high density area. Economies <strong>of</strong> density would therefore appear<br />

to constitute a significant entry barrier into this market and protect Greenstar<br />

from potential competition in the relevant market.<br />

The DoEHLG consultation on Regulation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Sector noted that<br />

excessive pr<strong>of</strong>its may be generated for the supplier in a situation where there is<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


competition in the market, as in Ireland. 70 Dunne et al. assert that illegal dumping<br />

has increased in recent years, although it must be noted that the rise could be<br />

attributed to a number <strong>of</strong> factors including increased reporting <strong>of</strong> dumping, a rise in<br />

awareness <strong>of</strong> the legislation, and the linked issue (to the one discussed here) <strong>of</strong> the<br />

manner <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use. 71<br />

Local governments have a legal responsibility to deal with waste arising in their<br />

jurisdictions though the prevailing legislation does not require households to opt into<br />

a service. The OECD notes that when the service is fully privatised (as it is in 67% <strong>of</strong><br />

the cases) local authorities do not have recorded evidence <strong>of</strong> the households who are<br />

part <strong>of</strong> a waste collection scheme. 72<br />

An additional issue in the Irish context is the application <strong>of</strong> the proximity principle.<br />

This principle states that the most sustainable way to dispose <strong>of</strong> waste is using the<br />

facilities closest to the area in which the waste has been generated. This has been<br />

targeted as one <strong>of</strong> the causes for the lack <strong>of</strong> development <strong>of</strong> innovative waste<br />

infrastructure in the country. A recent report for Repak notes that Ireland has suffered<br />

due to the current state <strong>of</strong> infrastructure. 73 Ireland relies on other countries to<br />

process the waste collected for recycling. The recent fall in prices <strong>of</strong> material to be<br />

processed has affected the Irish market considerably and led to stockpiling <strong>of</strong><br />

recovered material. 74<br />

The consultation paper on waste states that there is a trend toward market<br />

consolidation for the service providers. Vertical and horizontal integration have led to<br />

small firms being bought out by larger competitors. The OECD warns that vertical and<br />

horizontal integration can effect competition and thus should be monitored by<br />

competition authorities. 75 Indeed, experience suggests it is important for tenders to<br />

attract an adequate number <strong>of</strong> bids in order to ensure bidders <strong>of</strong>fer competitive<br />

prices for the service being tendered.<br />

In short, it is less than clear that competition in the market is leading to the provision<br />

<strong>of</strong> an economically efficient and environmentally sound waste collection service in<br />

Ireland.<br />

70 DoEHLG (2006) Regulation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Sector: Consultation Paper,<br />

http://www.environ.ie/en/Publications/Environment/<strong>Waste</strong>/<strong>Waste</strong><strong>Management</strong>/FileDownLoad,1446,<br />

en.pdf<br />

71 L. Dunne, F. Convery and L. Gallagher (2008) An investigation into waste charges in Ireland, with<br />

emphasis on public acceptability, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, pp 2826 – 2834.<br />

72 OECD (2008) Ireland: Toward an Integrated Public Service, Paris: OECD, available at:<br />

http://www.oecd.org/document/31/0,3343,en_2649_33735_40529119_1_1_1_1,00.html<br />

73 Bacon and Associates (2008) Examination <strong>of</strong> Impact <strong>of</strong> Recent Price Collapse in Markets for<br />

Recyclate Materials and Required Intervention, Report for Repak, available at:<br />

http://www.repak.ie/files/Bacon%20Report%20on%20<strong>Waste</strong>%20Markets,%20Nov.%202008_1.pdf<br />

74 It is important to understand the degree to which difficulties arising in marketing materials are<br />

related to material quality (and are, therefore, potentially amenable to being addressed by collectors<br />

and sorting facilities, or whether ‘infrastructure’ would help in this respect.<br />

75 OECD (2000) Competition in Local Services: Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, DAFFE/CLP(2000)13.<br />

48<br />

29/09/09


3.3 Market Failure<br />

Currently in Ireland waste management follows a free market structure. Institutional<br />

economists argue that no markets are free and all markets are structured by the<br />

state and other bodies. The institutions form the basis <strong>of</strong> a market. Institutions in this<br />

sense are rules and norms which form the area in which the actors compete. 76 In<br />

Ireland competition has been left relatively unregulated. However, it is important that<br />

the institutions are designed with careful consideration for the long term aims <strong>of</strong><br />

waste management.<br />

Warner, noting that some services should be considered natural monopolies,<br />

identifies waste as one such service. 77 Currently waste policies have not been<br />

developed to treat waste as a natural monopoly. There is a divergence between<br />

individual preferences and public preferences which manifest themselves in low<br />

service coverage, issues <strong>of</strong> illegal dumping and burning (which the collectors do not<br />

have to consider in their private calculus), and a reduced quality <strong>of</strong> service at a given<br />

price (reflecting the failure to capitalise on economies <strong>of</strong> density). Ironically, the<br />

private sector market for the provision <strong>of</strong> treatment infrastructure is effectively<br />

constrained by its ability to develop bankable propositions in the absence <strong>of</strong> security<br />

<strong>of</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> waste for subsequent treatment.<br />

An issue which has emerged as a result <strong>of</strong> the set <strong>of</strong> institutions that are in place is<br />

the prospect <strong>of</strong> market failure. Market failure indicates that the assumptions made<br />

about the market are incorrect and that one party is being made better <strong>of</strong>f at the<br />

expense <strong>of</strong> the other party i.e. the market is no longer efficient in the Pareto sense.<br />

Some possible market failures are indicated in Table 3-1.<br />

76 See, for example, Daniel W. Bromley (1989) Economic Interests and Institutions: The Conceptual<br />

Foundations <strong>of</strong> Public <strong>Policy</strong>, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.<br />

77 M. Warner (2008) Reversing privatization, rebalancing government reform: Markets, deliberation<br />

and planning, <strong>Policy</strong> and Society 27, pp 163–174<br />

49<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 3-1: Potential Market Failures in Irish <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Services<br />

50<br />

29/09/09<br />

Market Market Failure Failure<br />

Relevance Relevance to to Irish Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Market Power (the ability <strong>of</strong> an<br />

incumbent to alter the price <strong>of</strong> a<br />

service)<br />

Network externalities (the use <strong>of</strong> a<br />

service by a customer changes the<br />

value for other users)<br />

Imperfect Information<br />

Externalities –<br />

Environmental/Consumption/Other<br />

Regulatory Capture (when the<br />

regulatory body operates in favour<br />

<strong>of</strong> one particular interest group)<br />

Government Failure<br />

The local authorities could potentially exercise<br />

market power in their dual role as regulator and<br />

supplier.<br />

Incumbents may make market entry difficult by<br />

manipulating prices to ensure they maintain a<br />

captive market.<br />

Inefficiencies may occur due to the provision <strong>of</strong><br />

services by several operators in one area, and the<br />

varying take-up rates <strong>of</strong> the services on <strong>of</strong>fer.<br />

Collection services exhibit economies <strong>of</strong> density<br />

which are denied if multiple operators do compete in<br />

the market<br />

Full information is not available to the consumer<br />

regarding the quality <strong>of</strong> the waste collection service,<br />

resulting in imperfect information in the market<br />

Prices do not fully reflect the externalities associated<br />

with waste, so prices will not convey appropriate<br />

incentives to consumers.<br />

Local authorities have the power to regulate the<br />

market and may use this power in support <strong>of</strong> their<br />

own interests.<br />

It could be argued that the local authorities have<br />

failed to adequately account for the needs <strong>of</strong> service<br />

users.<br />

The Competition Authority also gave a large number <strong>of</strong> examples where competitive<br />

tendering appeared to generate economic benefits: 78<br />

� Kemper and Quigley (1976) estimates for the U.S. that competitive markets<br />

are 25% to 36% more expensive than a single collector, and that contract or<br />

78 The Competition Authority (2005) Decision <strong>of</strong> The Competition Authority (Case COM/108/02)<br />

concerning Alleged Excessive Pricing by Greenstar Holdings in the Provision <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Collection Services in Northeast Wicklow, 30 th August 2005, available at:<br />

http://tca.ie/search.aspx?SearchTerm=e/05/002


51<br />

franchise agreements reduce the costs over municipal collections by another<br />

13% to 30% (depending on the level <strong>of</strong> service). They found a loss <strong>of</strong> density<br />

economies to increase the costs <strong>of</strong> non-franchised suppliers.<br />

� Having observed data for 340 cities in the U.S., Stevens (1978) found the<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> exclusive market areas to private operators (e.g., via bidding<br />

procedures) to be 26% to 48% cheaper than a competitive private market and<br />

27% to 37% cheaper than municipal provision.<br />

� Before the introduction <strong>of</strong> compulsory competitive tendering in the UK in<br />

1988, Domberger et al. (1986) published a study on the effects <strong>of</strong> contracting<br />

out household refuse collection in the UK. They concluded cost savings <strong>of</strong><br />

22% in those municipalities where there was competitive tendering <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste collection services to private operators with no evidence that<br />

this was at the expense <strong>of</strong> service quality. They also found cost savings <strong>of</strong> 17%<br />

in those areas where the contract was awarded in-house.<br />

� Szymanski and Wilkins (1993) and Szymanski (1996) have confirmed<br />

Domberger et al.’s results. Szymanksi also found no evidence for the UK to<br />

support the notion that cost savings were attributable to quality reductions.<br />

� Ohlsson (1998) reported comparable efficiency gains for contracting out in<br />

Sweden.<br />

� In Denmark surveys showed that in 1990-1991 those Danish municipalities<br />

that had made use <strong>of</strong> competitive tendering experienced an average cost<br />

saving <strong>of</strong> 10%.<br />

� A comparison by Reeves and Barrows (2000) <strong>of</strong> the costs for certain<br />

contracting local authorities in Ireland before and after they contracted out<br />

refuse collection services indicated average cost savings for those authorities<br />

<strong>of</strong> 33.5%. A comparison <strong>of</strong> the average unit cost <strong>of</strong> contracting authorities<br />

versus authorities still engaged in public provision <strong>of</strong> the service for the three<br />

years 1993-95 indicated lower costs <strong>of</strong> around 46% on average for<br />

contracting authorities. Furthermore, it was found that the incidence <strong>of</strong><br />

efficiency was much greater amongst authorities that contracted out the<br />

service.<br />

� In a survey on solid waste collection services in Canadian municipalities in<br />

2001, McDavid found that on average public producers have higher costs<br />

than contracted private producers and that municipalities that competitively<br />

bid their solid waste collection contract enjoy significantly lower costs per<br />

household.<br />

� In an analysis <strong>of</strong> the cost structure <strong>of</strong> a sample <strong>of</strong> Italian waste collection<br />

firms, Antonioli and Filippini (2002) found franchised monopoly, rather than<br />

side-by-side competition, to be the most efficient form <strong>of</strong> production<br />

organization in the household waste collection industry and the only way <strong>of</strong><br />

introducing competition into this sector to be via competitive tendering to<br />

assign the provision <strong>of</strong> the service. They found further that the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste collectors were not operating at the optimal scale.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


52<br />

� In 2003 Dijkgraaf and Gradus similarly estimated cost savings <strong>of</strong> approx. 15-<br />

20% from contracting out refuse collection in the Netherlands. 79<br />

� A survey by the Norwegian Competition Authority suggests that quality was not<br />

significantly affected by competitive tendering in Norway. 39% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

municipalities surveyed said that quality had increased and 52% said that<br />

quality had stayed the same with competitive tendering. Only 8% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

municipalities surveyed said that quality had deteriorated.<br />

� A UK study found that in the case where a contract is competitively tendered<br />

to an outside private contractor, three-quarters <strong>of</strong> the 22% cost savings<br />

identified can be attributed to improvements in technical efficiency (i.e., more<br />

efficient use <strong>of</strong> workers and capital equipment) rather than lower input prices.<br />

3.4 Other Country Experience <strong>of</strong> Competition in the Market<br />

In this Section, we briefly review the situation in one other country which has adopted<br />

the approach <strong>of</strong> competition in the market, and comment more briefly on the<br />

experience <strong>of</strong> another.<br />

3.4.1 Poland<br />

Poland has a similar waste management system in operation to Ireland. Similar local<br />

governmental systems exist with the addition <strong>of</strong> a district level (municipality, district<br />

and regional levels). Many services were privatised following the introduction <strong>of</strong> a<br />

democratic rule in Poland. Householders and business pay a fee to waste operators<br />

for a waste collection / disposal service. Household waste fees are set dependent on<br />

the size <strong>of</strong> container and the frequency <strong>of</strong> collection chosen. Each household is<br />

obliged to maintain a contract with a waste operator. However, the low rate <strong>of</strong> service<br />

coverage shows that this control is lacking and waste producers have opted-out <strong>of</strong> the<br />

service.<br />

An article published in the European Environmental Press claims that the high<br />

fragmentation <strong>of</strong> the waste collection market results in very low standards <strong>of</strong><br />

service. 80 It has been noted that the economics are unfavourable because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

collection inefficiencies resulting from different collection companies collect waste<br />

from households on the same street.<br />

Due to the set up <strong>of</strong> the system, where there is no financing <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

management system from central government, means that waste management<br />

cannot be organised as government might wish. Movement up the waste hierarchy,<br />

79 Strictly speaking, this example does not highlight the benefits <strong>of</strong> competition for, as opposed to<br />

competition in, the market. Rather, it suggests lower cost from a tendered service than one provided by<br />

a local authority beforehand.<br />

80 EEP (2008) Systematic waste management systems lacking in Poland says EU, Published March<br />

14 th 2008, Accessed 13 th October 2008, http://waste.environmentalexpert.com/resultEachPressRelease.aspx?cid=6725&codi=28996&idproducttype=8&level=0<br />

29/09/09


as set out by the EU is limited in Poland, with 97% <strong>of</strong> waste landfilled according to the<br />

EEP. 81 This can be attributed to the following factors:<br />

53<br />

� Limited opportunity for separate collection <strong>of</strong> recoverable materials, potentially<br />

reflecting the combination <strong>of</strong> an open market for waste collection, and the<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> policies ‘structuring’ the market;<br />

� A competitive market leading to consumer choice and the option to opt out <strong>of</strong><br />

collection altogether. This, in turn, is hampered by:<br />

• Municipalities not having control over waste collectors or disposal;<br />

• <strong>Waste</strong> collection services only serving a portion <strong>of</strong> the total population;<br />

• Municipalities not generally able to charge local taxation so there being<br />

no funds available to take up management responsibility for waste;<br />

� Resultant high levels <strong>of</strong> tipping – <strong>of</strong>ten creating habitual tipping points around<br />

municipalities; and<br />

� Low costs <strong>of</strong> disposal. In particular this diminishes the business case to<br />

commence separate collection.<br />

A regional system with the aim <strong>of</strong> coordinating all the services in Poland has been<br />

proposed.<br />

3.4.2 Finland<br />

It is interesting to observe what has happened in the case <strong>of</strong> household waste<br />

collection where ‘competition in the market’ exists. At the time <strong>of</strong> the OECD study on<br />

this subject, some US and Finnish cities had adopted a system allowing competition<br />

in the market. 82 61 percent <strong>of</strong> the municipalities in Finland adopted a system where<br />

householders contract with waste collection companies for waste services. However,<br />

Finland does have a maximum price for charging and a stipulation on quality <strong>of</strong><br />

service provided.<br />

Following the OECD 2000 report, several local authorities in Finland switched to<br />

competitive tendering to raise rates <strong>of</strong> coverage. The first reason for this change is<br />

the costs associated with enforcing the requirement on households to purchase<br />

waste collection services. 83 Secondly, studies have shown that prices for waste<br />

collection in Finland seem to be higher for those municipalities which have<br />

competition for the market (i.e. a tendering service). The OECD noted that collection<br />

81 EEP (2008) Systematic waste management systems lacking in Poland says EU, Published March<br />

14 th 2008, Accessed 13 th October 2008, http://waste.environmentalexpert.com/resultEachPressRelease.aspx?cid=6725&codi=28996&idproducttype=8&level=0<br />

82 OECD (2000) Competition in Local Services: Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, DAFFE/CLP(2000)13.<br />

83 Typically, where households do not pay for any service, they either ‘free ride’ by using litter services,<br />

or other people’s bins, or CA sites where these are free at the point <strong>of</strong> use, or they dump, litter or burn<br />

their waste. None <strong>of</strong> these is desirable, though the different options are undesirable for different<br />

reasons.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


costs were 20-25 percent higher in regions where there was competition in the<br />

market as opposed to competitive tendering. 84<br />

The first reason given above is an important one. In principle, competition in the<br />

market could be ‘made to work’. However, it seems likely to us that the scope <strong>of</strong> the<br />

regulations and institutions which would be required to achieve this would be so<br />

complex as to make such an outcome both difficult and costly to achieve.<br />

3.5 Competition for the Market<br />

The Competition Authority notes that if a competitive tendering process were applied<br />

to the Irish market it would ‘work better’ for consumers. 85 It suggested that if a<br />

tendering process for waste contracts were used, a number <strong>of</strong> the problems<br />

associated with competition in the market could be avoided:<br />

54<br />

29/09/09<br />

on the basis <strong>of</strong> The Competition Authority’s extensive enquiries into household<br />

waste collection, it appears that the market for household waste collection is<br />

not working well for consumers. One solution - even if it could be<br />

demonstrated that Greenstar charged excessive prices – would be price<br />

regulation. Neither The Competition Authority nor the courts are equipped for<br />

such regulation. Furthermore, a waste regulator would also face a very difficult<br />

if not impossible task <strong>of</strong> setting prices, either on a State-wide or regional<br />

basis, since it is unlikely to have the information to set the competitive price.<br />

Costs and market conditions vary widely across the State.<br />

In The Competition Authority’s view there are better alternatives than a<br />

regulator to set prices for household waste collection. In the countries<br />

reviewed the predominant form <strong>of</strong> service provision in household waste<br />

collection is via competitive tendering. This international experience<br />

demonstrates that competitive tendering is the best method <strong>of</strong> ensuring that<br />

household waste collection providers deliver consumers good service at<br />

competitive prices. This system <strong>of</strong> competition for for the market should replace<br />

the existing model <strong>of</strong> competition within the market, i.e., where waste<br />

providers compete side-by-side with each other.<br />

Competition for the market would be set up to control the natural monopoly that is<br />

municipal waste collection. For the process to be efficient, as many service providers<br />

as possible should be competing for the tender (which would be <strong>of</strong>fered on a regular<br />

basis). If local government were to be one <strong>of</strong> the bodies putting themselves forward to<br />

tender the concern about the dual role <strong>of</strong> the local authority would be addressed<br />

while simultaneously ensuring the maximum number <strong>of</strong> competitors for the market.<br />

84 OECD (2000) Competition in Local Services: Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, DAFFE/CLP(2000)13.<br />

85 The Competition Authority (2005) Decision <strong>of</strong> The Competition Authority (Case COM/108/02)<br />

concerning Alleged Excessive Pricing by Greenstar Holdings in the Provision <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Collection Services in Northeast Wicklow, 30 th August 2005, available at:<br />

http://tca.ie/search.aspx?SearchTerm=e/05/002


The beneficial network effects, or economies <strong>of</strong> density, should be enhanced in a<br />

competitive tendering environment. The instances <strong>of</strong> cherry picking <strong>of</strong> customers<br />

should disappear also.<br />

55<br />

� There is a relatively limited level <strong>of</strong> sunk investment in the case <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

collection. There are no long-lived assets in waste collection and there are well<br />

developed second-hand / lease markets for the only assets <strong>of</strong> any importance<br />

(the vehicles). Probably the major investment in fixed assets relates to depots.<br />

There may be some investment by a firm in good customer relations, but to an<br />

extent this can be contractually verified;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> collection is a sufficiently homogeneous service that potential bidders<br />

could, in principle, gain a good understanding <strong>of</strong> the costs involved in waste<br />

collection by direct experience in other city markets. The incumbent’s<br />

information advantage is therefore likely to be weak; 86<br />

� In the case <strong>of</strong> waste collection the basic service quality parameters (frequency<br />

<strong>of</strong> collection, services provided, levels <strong>of</strong> customer complaints) can be<br />

sufficiently well specified to allow effective quality regulation.<br />

Other authors have also pointed out that the cost <strong>of</strong> service disruption is<br />

comparatively low. 87<br />

The OECD provides a survey <strong>of</strong> studies that attempt to measure the efficiency gains<br />

from competitive tendering. Generally, these studies suggest that tendering leads to<br />

significant efficiency gains without convincing evidence that this leads generally to<br />

lower quality <strong>of</strong> service. According to the OECD, in the tendering process, attention<br />

should be paid to: 88<br />

1. The geographic region over which collection services are to be provided should<br />

be large enough to allow successful firms to exploit economies <strong>of</strong> scale and<br />

density;<br />

2. Where the size <strong>of</strong> the city or district is much larger than the minimum efficient<br />

scale <strong>of</strong> collection, the OECD suggests breaking up the region into several<br />

smaller pieces and tendering each piece separately. This allows for<br />

performance comparisons between the firms serving the different regions,<br />

reduces the disruption associated with loss <strong>of</strong> service from a single firm and<br />

enhances the likelihood that several firms will be in a position to compete<br />

when the time comes for re-tendering;<br />

86 It should be stated that this does not necessarily mean that incumbents do not have an advantage<br />

in other strategically important ways (for example, location <strong>of</strong> depots, or ownership <strong>of</strong> local sorting<br />

facilities, or local landfill void, etc. However, the procurement process itself can, when sufficient care is<br />

taken, be designed to negate these advantages.<br />

87 M. Walls (2003) How Local Governments Structure Contract with Private Firms: Economic Theory<br />

and Evidence on Solid <strong>Waste</strong> and Recycling Contracts, Resources for the Future Discussion Paper 03-<br />

62.<br />

88 OECD (2000) Competition in Local Services: Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, DAFFE/CLP(2000)13.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


56<br />

3. Successful collusion in the tendering process requires the ability to detect and<br />

punish deviations from the cartel agreement. Therefore, the OECD argues that,<br />

from the competition perspective, it is preferable to use sealed bid auctions,<br />

without disclosing the results. 89 According to the OECD, concerns about<br />

political favouritism could be met by the establishment <strong>of</strong> an independent<br />

agency with responsibility for overseeing all public tenders and with access to<br />

all <strong>of</strong> the bids.<br />

4. If competition in disposal facilities is limited or non-existent, firms which do not<br />

own disposal facilities will be at a competitive disadvantage in the tendering<br />

process for waste collection. In these cases, the OECD argues that potential<br />

collection firms should be guaranteed access to disposal facilities on nondiscriminatory<br />

grounds. An alternative and, according to the OECD, preferable<br />

solution is to separate ownership <strong>of</strong> disposal and collection facilities and/or to<br />

prevent owners <strong>of</strong> disposal facilities from participating in tenders for<br />

collection; 90<br />

5. In many cases, a division or subsidiary <strong>of</strong> the local government itself is in a<br />

position to provide the services, which are being purchased by tender.<br />

Competitive neutrality is ensured when public and private sector suppliers face<br />

identical regulatory, legal, financial and administrative arrangements. 91<br />

An interesting point is that much <strong>of</strong> the discussion in the literature relates largely to<br />

household waste collections. Yet the same is almost certainly true for waste collection<br />

from commercial premises. The question, therefore, is why this same logic should not<br />

be extended to commercial waste collections? We are not aware <strong>of</strong> the same level <strong>of</strong><br />

interest in this area since much interest in the contracting out <strong>of</strong> waste collection<br />

services relates to an interest in privatisation <strong>of</strong> public services. To the extent that<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> commercial waste is not a public service as such, the same interest does<br />

not appear to be present among researchers. Even so, the logic for similar, albeit<br />

appropriately adapted, approaches seems to be compelling.<br />

89 Evidently, this is a strange recommendation as ultimately, the result is easily knowable.<br />

90 The alternative – clearly favoured increasingly in the context <strong>of</strong> English procurements for municipal<br />

waste – is to ‘unbundle’ services and procure different service elements through discrete tendering<br />

processes (most notably, separating collection from contracts for residual waste treatment / disposal).<br />

This reflects a concern to enhance competition in the market, recognising that integrated contracts<br />

tend to favour larger players in the marketplace, with the specialised services which smaller<br />

companies might be able to <strong>of</strong>fer in collection being potentially overlooked. In short, the approach is<br />

more likely to deliver better value for money (see, for example, OGC (2006) Improving Competition and<br />

Capacity Planning in the Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Market, OGC Kelly Report to the Financial Secretary to the<br />

Treasury, May 2006<br />

http://www.ogc.gov.uk/documents/OGC_Kelly_Report_to_the_Financial_Secretary_to_the_Treasury_-<br />

_May_2006(1).pdf )<br />

91 This point – the desirability <strong>of</strong> enabling public and private sector companies to compete in the<br />

market - is a theme <strong>of</strong> the work <strong>of</strong> Dijkgraaf and Gradus (see, for example, E. Dijkgraaf and R. H. J. M.<br />

Gradus (2005) Collusion in the Dutch <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Market, 31 January 2005).<br />

29/09/09


3.6 Recommendations<br />

What is <strong>of</strong>ten described as ‘competition for the market’ has the potential to address<br />

several <strong>of</strong> the issues that appear to be problematic in the waste collection market,<br />

and which result from competition in the market. The most fundamental change is to<br />

place the responsibility for household collection firmly in the hands <strong>of</strong> local<br />

authorities, with the authorities being responsible for tendering the service out to<br />

private operators should they wish to do so. This has the potential to:<br />

57<br />

• Enable collectors to benefit from economies <strong>of</strong> density, so reducing the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

service delivery to the users;<br />

• As a result, increase the take-up <strong>of</strong> services across a given geographical area;<br />

• Enable the quality and scope <strong>of</strong> the collection service to be specified through<br />

the tendering mechanism;<br />

• Squeeze out monopoly rents where service operators are operating as a local<br />

monopoly; and<br />

• Enable a stronger link to be made between the collection and treatment <strong>of</strong><br />

waste, improving the prospects for development <strong>of</strong> the desired infrastructure.<br />

In short, it should allow for similar or greater environmental quality to be attained at<br />

lower cost (or alternatively, greater environmental benefits will be generated at the<br />

same cost). Some key questions still remain, however.<br />

3.6.1 Should Local Authorities be Able to Provide the Household Collection<br />

Service?<br />

The above discussion has presented two main options:<br />

1. Competition in the market, where no one body has ‘control’ over household<br />

waste, and private and public operators may compete for custom on a day-today<br />

basis; and<br />

2. Competition for the market, where a body which has control for household<br />

waste – the local authority - tenders out that service.<br />

The second approach presumes that the body with control over household waste<br />

does, indeed, tender the service out. In reality, a third option exists in which the<br />

density <strong>of</strong> logistics is ensured, and the coherence <strong>of</strong> service provision is made more<br />

likely, but where the local authority itself operates the waste collection service.<br />

In Ireland, it seems unlikely that many local authorities would wish to re-enter a<br />

market they have already vacated. In many authorities, therefore, it might be<br />

expected that the natural approach would be to tender the service out to a private<br />

operator.<br />

In some local authority areas, however, the authorities retain a strong presence as<br />

the direct provider <strong>of</strong> services. In this context, local authorities could not be forced to<br />

tender the service out to private contractors (for legal reasons). They could, indeed,<br />

choose to operate the service themselves. However, they should be strongly<br />

encouraged to market-test their service in order, periodically, to demonstrate that<br />

their in-house <strong>of</strong>fering represents value for money to residents.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


In these situations, it would be appropriate to have in place benchmarking<br />

mechanisms for the costs <strong>of</strong> collection services so as to assess the costs and quality<br />

<strong>of</strong> service <strong>of</strong> the different operators. We strongly recommend that the benchmarking<br />

data are made a reporting requirement for local authorities. There is a dearth <strong>of</strong><br />

quality information on collection costs in Ireland, and this type <strong>of</strong> reporting<br />

requirement would do much to fill the existing void.<br />

3.6.2 How Will Costs be Recovered?<br />

It is important to note that, as far as household waste is concerned, in most EU<br />

Member States (and several other countries besides), households pay for the waste<br />

management services through a combination <strong>of</strong>:<br />

58<br />

• Central government taxation;<br />

• Local government taxation; and<br />

• A variable ‘user pays’ element.<br />

In Ireland, the middle <strong>of</strong> these three tiers is absent.<br />

The attraction <strong>of</strong> the three tiered approach is that with the exception <strong>of</strong> the user pays<br />

element, the costs <strong>of</strong> the service are met by payments which householders are<br />

required to make. Given that, in such countries, the variable element either does not<br />

exist, or constitutes (on average) something <strong>of</strong> the order 30-50% <strong>of</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong> the<br />

service, then there is relatively little incentive for households not to use the service. 92<br />

The question arises as to how, with a tendering approach in place, the costs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

service would be met by the users? If the costs were to be met through payments by<br />

households, might it not be the case that the costs would still be deemed too high for<br />

some customers to consider availing themselves <strong>of</strong> the service on <strong>of</strong>fer?<br />

This is an important problem to resolve. Ireland has no local taxes. We would suggest<br />

that:<br />

1. In the absence <strong>of</strong> such taxes, it would be preferable for a significant proportion<br />

<strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> service provision to be met through central government<br />

taxation. Local authorities would be paid an amount based upon a formula<br />

92 There is a fundamental misunderstanding <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> basic concepts <strong>of</strong> how waste services are<br />

financed, and <strong>of</strong> operational issues, in the OECD’s discussion <strong>of</strong> cost recovery in the waste sector (see<br />

OECD (2008) Ireland: Toward an Integrated Public Service, Paris: OECD, available at:<br />

http://www.oecd.org/document/31/0,3343,en_2649_33735_40529119_1_1_1_1,00.html). The<br />

OECD praises the Irish model for the extent <strong>of</strong> ‘cost recovery’, conveniently overlooking that costs are<br />

recovered in all municipal waste collection systems, but rarely with high proportions <strong>of</strong> that cost being<br />

recovered through variable charges. The OECD also fails to draw the link between the high level <strong>of</strong> ‘cost<br />

recovery’ and the low level <strong>of</strong> service take-up. The two are (obviously) linked as the price <strong>of</strong> the service<br />

at the point <strong>of</strong> delivery affects demand for it. Particularly in the Irish situation, and in advance <strong>of</strong> any<br />

measure to require householders to make use <strong>of</strong> a service, the situation least likely to engender<br />

service take up is the one the OECD seems to be promoting. Furthermore, under pay by use systems,<br />

for reasons associated with revenue stability (the need to ensure the costs <strong>of</strong> the service are covered)<br />

applying high variable rates is apt to cause problems in terms <strong>of</strong> early implementation <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use.<br />

This problem is widely discussed in the literature regarding pay-by-use (see Appendix 8.0).<br />

29/09/09


59<br />

which was designed to reflect a defined proportion – <strong>of</strong> the order 50% - <strong>of</strong> the<br />

total costs <strong>of</strong> service provision;<br />

2. In the absence <strong>of</strong> funds coming from either central or local taxation, it<br />

becomes important to have in place some counterpart law which requires<br />

households to avail themselves <strong>of</strong> the collection service provided. In essence,<br />

this mimics the Danish approach, in which households are required to pay,<br />

first and foremost, for waste collection services. In the absence <strong>of</strong> such a<br />

measure, which is probably necessary under 1, above, also, tenderers could<br />

not be sure that households would take-up the service they were <strong>of</strong>fering (so<br />

that tenders would include an upward adjustment to account for the risk <strong>of</strong><br />

non-use by residents); and<br />

3. In either case, and so as to reduce the costs <strong>of</strong> waste management at the<br />

point <strong>of</strong> delivery, the costs <strong>of</strong> operating separate collection schemes and for<br />

recycling material should be met, as far as possible, in their entirety by<br />

obligated producers. In addition, recognising that there remain pecuniary<br />

externalities upon collectors related to the unrecycled proportion <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

targeted under producer responsibility, and recognising also the desirability <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling, the targets for recycling <strong>of</strong> the targeted materials should be suitably<br />

ambitious, and there should be sanctions applied in the event <strong>of</strong> failure to<br />

meet these targets. The European Commission’s proposal for a revised<br />

Directive on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment suggests that where<br />

appropriate, Member States should encourage producers to finance all the<br />

cost occurring for collection facilities for WEEE from private households. This is<br />

in line with the polluter pays principle. The implication <strong>of</strong> this proposal is that<br />

a) producer responsibility measures need to be re-visited to ensure that all<br />

relevant costs fall fully upon producers; and b) the targets which producers are<br />

required to meet are suitably ambitious.<br />

Either 2) or more palatably, a combination <strong>of</strong> 2) and one, or both, <strong>of</strong> 1) and 3), would<br />

be necessary to ensure that households do not simply opt out <strong>of</strong> the service, with<br />

potentially detrimental impacts for the value for money gained from tenders for<br />

service provision. It should be noted that both <strong>of</strong> these approaches also enhance the<br />

prospects for setting a more uniform charging structure for household service<br />

provision at an average level. By this, we do not mean setting one type <strong>of</strong> charging<br />

system, rather that the charges should follow a specific structure to maintain revenue<br />

stability.<br />

3.6.3 Treatment Facilities<br />

Whatever body takes charge for tendering collection, that body effectively has the<br />

ability to control the waste once it has been collected (for example, it can specify the<br />

delivery <strong>of</strong> different wastes to specified destinations). This makes it possible for the<br />

body controlling that waste to tender for treatments appropriate to the way in which<br />

the material is collected. This would give security <strong>of</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> the material to suppliers<br />

<strong>of</strong> treatment capacity.<br />

In the majority <strong>of</strong> jurisdictions outside Ireland, the developer <strong>of</strong> a given waste<br />

treatment facility for dealing with household waste (municipal waste is more broadly<br />

defined in Ireland than in other EU Member States) is typically given a high level <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


certainty in respect <strong>of</strong> waste being delivered to the facility, not necessarily with<br />

guaranteed minimum tonnages, and not necessarily guaranteed for excessively<br />

lengthy periods. However, the nature <strong>of</strong> such contracts, and the payment<br />

mechanisms included within them, is usually such as to reduce the risk associated<br />

with the development to a significant degree.<br />

Much depends upon the procurement route chosen, but the reduction in risk to which<br />

the developer is exposed serves two important purposes:<br />

60<br />

29/09/09<br />

a) it makes the development less risky from the financial point <strong>of</strong> view,<br />

increasing the likelihood that the development does, indeed, go ahead;<br />

and<br />

b) if it does receive the necessary financial backing, it is likely, other<br />

things being equal, to reduce the cost <strong>of</strong> the facility to the procuring<br />

party. Having said this, the costs will be significantly affected by the<br />

approach to procurement used.<br />

In the current context, for Ireland, these considerations are <strong>of</strong> some significance. The<br />

context is one where there is an urgent need to develop facilities.<br />

If bidders are asked to tender for facilities with no substantive guarantee attaching to<br />

the supply <strong>of</strong> waste into the facility, effectively, they are being asked to absorb the<br />

risk related to the supply <strong>of</strong> waste into the facility. It is not clear what the role <strong>of</strong> a<br />

tendering process is in this context, since the development shades into being a<br />

merchant investment, where the developer simply introduces a facility into a<br />

competitive market place.<br />

Competition for the market would enable greater certainty to be given to developers,<br />

in the context <strong>of</strong> managed procurements, as to the supply <strong>of</strong> material into a given<br />

facility. This ought to rationalise the development <strong>of</strong> facilities, and make tenders<br />

attractive to a range <strong>of</strong> bidders, not least those who see less merit in taking<br />

significant commercial risks in developing facilities. This is likely to be <strong>of</strong> particular<br />

significance at the current time with access to credit severely constrained, and those<br />

<strong>of</strong>fering credit seeking to de-risk their investments as far as possible. Ongoing UK<br />

experience with public private partnership (PPP) projects provides some sobering<br />

experience in this regard. 93<br />

3.6.4 Managing the Transition<br />

The issue <strong>of</strong> who has what right to control the flow <strong>of</strong> which wastes into what facilities<br />

is a matter <strong>of</strong> legal disputes at present. However, more broadly, the issues currently<br />

giving rise to considerable disquiet, angst and no little uncertainty appear to focus<br />

upon (based on our discussions with various bodies):<br />

93 See, for example, The Observer (2009) Treasury Set to Bail Out Second Recession-hit PFI, 10 May<br />

2009, http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2009/may/10/pfi-vt-bail-out-treasury and letsrecycle.com<br />

(2009) Delight at greater Manchester PFI deal Close,<br />

http://www.letsrecycle.com/do/ecco.py/view_item?listid=38&listcatid=218&listitemid=51746 .


61<br />

1. Whether the private sector has the right to compete for the provision <strong>of</strong><br />

services to households;<br />

2. Whether a local authority can direct waste which it does not itself collect into<br />

specific facilities, specifically, in the case <strong>of</strong> Dublin, whether collection permits<br />

could be specified such that this could occur;<br />

3. If the answer to 2) is ‘yes’, then under what circumstances could such<br />

direction into a facility whose position is in the lower tiers (recovery / disposal)<br />

<strong>of</strong> the waste hierarchy be said to compromise the movement <strong>of</strong> waste up the<br />

hierarchy.<br />

In addition, in respect <strong>of</strong> 2), we find it difficult to see how a local authority could avoid<br />

the charge that it was:<br />

1. Supporting the establishment <strong>of</strong> a monopoly on the part <strong>of</strong> the facility in<br />

question;<br />

2. Thereby, effectively opening up waste collectors to discriminatory pricing on<br />

the part <strong>of</strong> the operator; as well as<br />

3. Through affecting journey times to and from facilities, significantly affecting<br />

the costs <strong>of</strong> waste management on the part <strong>of</strong> both the providers and the<br />

users <strong>of</strong> the waste management service being provided.<br />

These matters are, in the existing legal framework, for the courts, and for the<br />

Competition Authority to decide upon. Their determinations will affect how one<br />

construes ‘the baseline’ from which it is intended that the situation should change.<br />

Our remit has been to propose policies which we believe would further the cause <strong>of</strong><br />

Irish waste management in terms, broadly speaking, <strong>of</strong> its overall performance in cost<br />

and environmental terms. Irrespective <strong>of</strong> the interpretation <strong>of</strong> existing law, therefore,<br />

we believe the recommendations to be the right ones for Ireland.<br />

However, there will be transition costs, and these will be affected by the decisions <strong>of</strong><br />

the courts (which will influence, for example, whether the actions <strong>of</strong> private actors in<br />

providing household waste collection services should be considered as a ‘public<br />

undertaking’, and hence, how any transition to a situation where local authorities<br />

have exclusive control over waste management might occur). Providing adequate<br />

time for the current incumbents to react and determining the appropriate<br />

geographical regions <strong>of</strong> tender also requires attention. Also, seeking to ensure<br />

‘competitive neutrality’, which is to say, seeking to ensure that advantages which a<br />

given bidder might possess are neutralised as far as possible, is an important step in<br />

implementing a system <strong>of</strong> competitive tendering.<br />

We take the view that if the proposed changes are announced some time in advance<br />

<strong>of</strong> when they are due to take effect, then this should allow for adjustment in the<br />

existing market to take place in anticipation <strong>of</strong> the proposed change. Equally, the lead<br />

time should not be excessive. The following issues are <strong>of</strong> relevance:<br />

1. Some local authorities may wish to develop single-client structures such that<br />

they let tenders jointly for collection services. We would encourage local<br />

authorities to consider the options without necessarily confining themselves to<br />

partners within the existing waste management planning regions;<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


62<br />

2. To have all local authorities tendering at once would be undesirable from the<br />

perspective <strong>of</strong> bidders, and would likely lead to a lack <strong>of</strong> competition for some<br />

tenders. Some phasing <strong>of</strong> tenders is likely to be necessary, and this is likely to<br />

require some co-ordination;<br />

3. There is likely to be a compelling need for upskilling <strong>of</strong> local authority staff in<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> the management <strong>of</strong> procurements for collection services. Some<br />

central support for the local authorities may well be warranted, with expertise<br />

made available to ensure procurement strategies maximise the likelihood that<br />

quality services will be delivered at an efficient price;<br />

4. The lead time <strong>of</strong> the principle assets in respect <strong>of</strong> collection are vehicles with a<br />

life-time <strong>of</strong> seven years or so. This sets an outer limit for the period <strong>of</strong><br />

adjustment;<br />

5. The longer is the period <strong>of</strong> adjustment allowed, the less likely are problems to<br />

arise in respect <strong>of</strong> complaints regarding stranded assets on the part <strong>of</strong><br />

unsuccessful bidders. Presumably, participants in the existing market are, in<br />

any case, aware that in principle, unless they are already beneficiaries <strong>of</strong><br />

existing tender processes, they could lose market share to competitors.<br />

Elsewhere, we have proposed a National Board for the oversight <strong>of</strong> an Irish <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plan. It is suggested that an early task <strong>of</strong> this Board would be to<br />

consider the outcome <strong>of</strong> the legal cases pending and then to make recommendations<br />

for the transition from the existing situation to one in which local authorities control,<br />

even where they do not operate (i.e. through tendering out the service), household<br />

waste collection.<br />

29/09/09


4.0 The Role <strong>of</strong> Local Authorities<br />

4.1 Functions as Regulator and Service Provider<br />

In Ireland, local authorities have two functions in the waste management sector. They<br />

are responsible for both providing waste collection and disposal services, and playing<br />

a role in the way in which these markets are structured and regulated. Often the<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> waste management services is contracted out to private firms; the<br />

alternative is the local authority providing this service.<br />

Regulatory responsibilities include:<br />

63<br />

� Issuing waste collection permits, and setting the terms <strong>of</strong> these;<br />

� Developing bylaws influencing, for example, the way waste materials are<br />

presented;<br />

� Responsibility for waste planning issues (ins<strong>of</strong>ar as these are not major<br />

projects – see below);<br />

� Determining applications for, and issuing, waste facility permits;<br />

� Controlling illegal dumping;<br />

� Monitoring compliance with regulations implementing producer responsibility<br />

with respect to packaging;<br />

� Monitoring waste disposal;<br />

� Collecting and providing data; and<br />

� Devising regional waste management plans (RWMPs).<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> operations, local authorities:<br />

� Can engage directly in waste collection activity;<br />

� Are involved in the operation <strong>of</strong> civic amenity sites;<br />

� May be involved in street cleaning and clean-up <strong>of</strong> fly-tips; and<br />

� Are likely to submit planning applications for landfills and other waste<br />

management facilities in their own right with a view to operating them.<br />

The task <strong>of</strong> regulating the market when combined with a business interest in the<br />

same market can lead to a conflict <strong>of</strong> interest. For example, if local authorities are<br />

operating a waste treatment operation, they may have a commercial to influence<br />

other collectors such that they deliver the collected waste to their own facility.<br />

Much <strong>of</strong> the literature in respect <strong>of</strong> environmental regulation highlights problems<br />

associated with the issue <strong>of</strong> ‘regulatory capture’. In the case <strong>of</strong> local authorities in the<br />

current context, it is clear that the possibility exists for such capture to be<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


institutionalised unless matters are handled with considerable sensitivity, and unless<br />

appropriate constraints are in place. This has been recognised by DoEHLG in its<br />

Consultation Paper on the Regulation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Sector: 94<br />

64<br />

29/09/09<br />

‘The private waste sector has highlighted the following main areas <strong>of</strong> concern<br />

to the industry:<br />

(a) Unlike their private sector counterparts, local authorities are not<br />

required to obtain collection permits in order to engage in the<br />

commercial collection <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

(b) Local authorities are required to undergo a less onerous<br />

registration process for certain waste activities, whereas their<br />

private sector counterparts are required to obtain waste permits<br />

for the same activities. Permitting is also more costly for the<br />

private sector.<br />

(c) The planning system operates differently for private sector and<br />

public sector projects. It takes longer to obtain planning<br />

permission for private sector projects than it does to obtain<br />

permission for local authority projects. In addition, while local<br />

authorities can obtain registration for their projects within a<br />

short timescale, the permitting <strong>of</strong> private sector projects can be<br />

subject to delays. Disparities in planning and permitting<br />

timescales may give local authorities an advantage over private<br />

waste companies in setting up their own waste facilities. The<br />

Strategic Infrastructure Bill seeks to address this issue.<br />

(d) The Environment Fund comprises monies raised through both<br />

the plastic bag levy and the landfill levy. The landfill levy is<br />

charged at €15 per tonne based on every tonne <strong>of</strong> waste which<br />

goes to landfill. Local authority waste infrastructure projects are<br />

part funded by the Environment Fund, however no funding is<br />

available for private sector waste projects despite the<br />

contribution that private sector waste companies make towards<br />

the landfill levy and ultimately the Environment Fund.<br />

(e) Local authorities and the private sector are both competing in<br />

the same market therefore it would be expected that they would<br />

operate under the same market conditions.’<br />

In addition, local authorities do not have to charge value-added tax (VAT) on the<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> waste services whereas private companies are required to do so. The<br />

OECD notes that local authorities have also been allowed to build landfill above the<br />

capacity set out in the regional waste management plans. It does, however, also note<br />

94 DoEHLG (2006) Regulation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Sector: Consultation Paper,<br />

http://www.environ.ie/en/Publications/Environment/<strong>Waste</strong>/<strong>Waste</strong><strong>Management</strong>/FileDownLoad,1446,<br />

en.pdf


that there have been no significant and conclusively demonstrated examples <strong>of</strong> a<br />

local authority using these powers to benefit their waste collection services.<br />

These issues appear to have the potential to distort competition. The Indecon Report,<br />

for example, noted that the lack <strong>of</strong> full cost recovery on the part <strong>of</strong> local authorities<br />

was likely to affect competition, not to mention, require additional revenue sources to<br />

support the services provided. 95 Allegations that additional time and cost are spent in<br />

the planning process, and that the difference in processes which the private sector<br />

and local authorities are required to go through to obtain permits impose additional<br />

administrative burdens on industry relative to local authorities, might not always be<br />

straightforward to substantiate conclusively, but nor are they so straightforward to<br />

dismiss out <strong>of</strong> hand.<br />

Finally, if it is the intention <strong>of</strong> the Government to engender genuine competition in the<br />

market, then save for support for matters such as dealing with legacy issues (where<br />

the past pattern <strong>of</strong> ownership <strong>of</strong> landfills might implicitly bias funding in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

local authorities), then the differing terms <strong>of</strong> access to the Environmental Fund also<br />

appear to have the potential to distort competition.<br />

Local authorities have traditionally occupied a strategic position in waste<br />

management. They have, historically, owned and operated landfills, and have been<br />

the main collectors <strong>of</strong> household waste. In the period following the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Act, one might reasonably assume that as costs increased, so local<br />

authorities, as landfill operators, may have sought to benefit from the scarcity <strong>of</strong> void<br />

space in the country. This could have allowed landfill prices to be raised above levels<br />

which might have prevailed in a more competitive market. In addition, where the<br />

same local authority both operated the household collection service and operated the<br />

landfill, there would have been scope for differential pricing in which commercial<br />

collectors making use <strong>of</strong> the site were effectively cross-subsidising the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

landfilling household waste.<br />

Furthermore, local authorities will also have had the power to engineer continuing<br />

scarcity <strong>of</strong> void space provision, so prolonging their somewhat privileged position. The<br />

potential for abuse <strong>of</strong> what is, effectively, market power appears to have been<br />

recognised in an ESRI report: 96<br />

65<br />

‘Where Local Authorities continue to be the only supplier <strong>of</strong> services in an<br />

area, there is a requirement to ensure that pricing reflects efficient levels <strong>of</strong><br />

operation. Currently, Local Authorities act as suppliers, planning authorities<br />

and environmental regulators in the waste management industry. This means<br />

they are potentially conflicted in dealings with private operators, which could<br />

distort competition. With each Local Authority acting as regulator, there is<br />

95 Indecon <strong>International</strong> in association with the Institute <strong>of</strong> Local Government Studies at University <strong>of</strong><br />

Birmingham (2006) Indecon <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Local Government Financing, Report Commissioned by the<br />

Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government.<br />

96 John FitzGerald and Edgar Morgenroth (2006) Ex-Ante Evaluation <strong>of</strong> the Investment Priorities for the<br />

National Development Plan 2007-2013, ESRI Report Commissioned by <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Finance,<br />

October 2006.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


66<br />

29/09/09<br />

scope for inconsistency geographically and temporally. A single regulatory<br />

structure applicable throughout the State would help encourage private<br />

participation in the market.’<br />

Whether such abuses actually occurred, or whether they did not, might be considered<br />

idle speculation. What may be at issue is that the existing system allows for the<br />

perception <strong>of</strong> abuses and grievances to persist. The question then becomes one <strong>of</strong><br />

whether these are sufficiently <strong>of</strong> concern to require change, and if so, what these<br />

changes should be.<br />

Eunomia noted, in previous work, that the varied roles <strong>of</strong> local authorities may have<br />

served to keep landfill gate fees high in the past. 97 When local authorities were the<br />

major operators <strong>of</strong> landfills, and where they required additional revenue to support<br />

their activities (especially following the eradication <strong>of</strong> rates), then it would have been<br />

useful to raise gate fees as a means <strong>of</strong> raising revenue for other services. Now, as<br />

more void space is consented, and as regional monopolies are weakened with the<br />

emergence <strong>of</strong> the private sector in landfilling, so gate fees appear to be falling. The<br />

arrival <strong>of</strong> the private sector in landfill operation might, therefore, have led to falling<br />

landfill gate fees, with the indirect effect <strong>of</strong> possibly giving rise to budgetary problems<br />

in other aspects <strong>of</strong> local government.<br />

This view is echoed in a Forfás report, which notes that landfill gate fees in Ireland the<br />

third highest <strong>of</strong> the eleven countries used in their analysis – that is after a drop from<br />

€135 in 2006 to €127 in 2007. 98 The current situation where the local authority has<br />

the power to regulate and participate in the market has caused inefficiencies. The<br />

OECD notes that private operators claim that when local authorities were the sole<br />

operators <strong>of</strong> landfills gate fees were used as a source <strong>of</strong> revenue. Following the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> a higher number <strong>of</strong> private landfill operators gate fees have fallen. 99<br />

It should be noted that the degree to which the local authorities’ role allows them to<br />

distort the market ‘in their favour’ is not entirely a ‘one-way’ consideration. The fact<br />

remains that local authorities have additional responsibilities in the operational<br />

sense, over and above the collection <strong>of</strong> waste, and the management <strong>of</strong> that collected<br />

waste, which are do not pre-occupy the private sector providers. These include cleanup<br />

<strong>of</strong> old landfills, operation <strong>of</strong> CA sites (and bring sites), provision <strong>of</strong> information /<br />

education and provision <strong>of</strong> street cleaning services, whilst local authorities may also<br />

operate waiver schemes for low-income households.<br />

97 Eunomia, with TOBIN (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Planning and Regulation in Ireland, Final Report for<br />

Greenstar.<br />

98 Forfás (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Benchmarking Analysis and <strong>Policy</strong> Priorities, available at:<br />

http://www.forfas.ie/media/forfas080528_waste_benchmarking.pdf. The point made by Forfas is fine<br />

ins<strong>of</strong>ar as it goes, but the reality is that <strong>of</strong> the ten countries and regions chosen, 6 (Massachusetts,<br />

Flanders, Austria, Netherlands, Sweden and Denmark) had implemented landfill bans <strong>of</strong> varying<br />

breadth. Consequently, for many wastes, the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling are effectively infinite unless some<br />

form <strong>of</strong> exemption can be found.<br />

99 OECD (2008) Ireland: Toward an Integrated Public Service, Paris: OECD, available at:<br />

http://www.oecd.org/document/31/0,3343,en_2649_33735_40529119_1_1_1_1,00.html


Local authorities have no obvious mechanism – other than charges to households,<br />

and on landfilled waste - through which to recover costs <strong>of</strong> other services which<br />

private sector operators do not need to <strong>of</strong>fer, especially in respect <strong>of</strong> the more ‘public<br />

good’ elements <strong>of</strong> the waste management service (such as street cleaning, controlling<br />

illegal dumping, etc.). It is not clear that receipts from the Environmental Fund would<br />

cover all these costs, so that authorities may be competing in the waste collection<br />

market from a position where they are seeking to recover costs, through their<br />

charges, which their competitors do not have to bear.<br />

Indeed, we may now be entering a period where, instead <strong>of</strong> landfill gate fees<br />

supporting the revenues required to operate waste services, the pendulum is<br />

swinging the other way, and local authorities would be required to raise revenues over<br />

and above the cost <strong>of</strong> provision <strong>of</strong> collection and treatment services in order to run<br />

other aspects <strong>of</strong> the waste management service, as well as to support clean-up <strong>of</strong> old<br />

landfills. 100 In such a situation, private sector operators would be able to operate<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itably in the collection market even with lower economies <strong>of</strong> density in collection.<br />

The perception <strong>of</strong> conflict clearly persists, and whilst instances <strong>of</strong> abuse <strong>of</strong> power<br />

might be considered, by many, to be largely anecdotal, such abuses could not be<br />

completely ruled out. The local authority clearly retains advantages by not being<br />

required to obtain permits or charge VAT.<br />

It is worth noting, in passing, that giving local authorities responsibility for the<br />

household waste collection service, and allowing them to tender out the service,<br />

would effectively make any perceived inequality, to the extent it exists, less relevant<br />

for the simple reason that there would be one provider <strong>of</strong> the household collection<br />

service in a given area.<br />

4.2 Moving Forward<br />

The aims <strong>of</strong> local authorities and the central government with respect to waste<br />

management are as follows:<br />

67<br />

� Prevention;<br />

� Reduction;<br />

� Recycling;<br />

� Sustainable disposal <strong>of</strong> other waste;<br />

� Integrated waste management approach; and<br />

� A more effective and equitable system <strong>of</strong> waste charging. 101<br />

100 See, for example, CCMA (2007) The Local Authority Perspective on the Realities <strong>of</strong> Irish <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong>, a Position Paper Presented by the City and County Managers’ Association, 23 rd April<br />

2007.<br />

101 EPA (1998) A <strong>Policy</strong> Statement: <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> – Changing Our Ways available at:<br />

http://www.epa.ie/downloads/pubs/waste/plans/epa_changing_our_ways_1998.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


It is widely suggested that the existing structure <strong>of</strong> responsibilities is not tenable.<br />

Such tensions as already exist could be heightened as waste management in Ireland<br />

moves into a phase in which major items <strong>of</strong> infrastructure will have to be developed.<br />

In such a situation, the potential for local authorities to exert their influence over the<br />

structure <strong>of</strong> the market to achieve market dominance could give rise to<br />

understandable concerns.<br />

One could start from the perspective that in order to eliminate the perception, and the<br />

possible reality <strong>of</strong>, a conflict <strong>of</strong> interest, two extreme possibilities exist:<br />

68<br />

� The local authority withdraws completely from service provision; and<br />

� The local authority withdraws completely from any regulatory role.<br />

Between these two extremes, clearly, there are many possibilities for some ‘middle<br />

ground’ to emerge. Such a middle ground would, <strong>of</strong> course, need to be considered<br />

very carefully to ensure that the respective roles did not engender potential for a<br />

continuation <strong>of</strong> real, or perceived, conflicts. The extremes serve, however, to highlight<br />

some <strong>of</strong> the key issues.<br />

At present the EPA is responsible for proactive waste management which includes<br />

providing information on waste prevention and implementing regulations e.g. the<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronics Equipment Directive. Other duties include drafting a<br />

hazardous waste management plan. 102<br />

The EPA could, in principle, replace the local authority as a regulator by assuming the<br />

regulatory roles <strong>of</strong> the local authority. This might make for more even application <strong>of</strong><br />

the regulatory apparatus, and ought to ensure that local authorities and the private<br />

sector are dealt with in a more even-handed basis.<br />

Taking the regulatory role away from the local authorities would enable centralisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the regulatory functions and level the playing field across actors in the sector. It<br />

would also enable local authorities to maintain, should they be sufficiently<br />

competitive, a presence as service providers within the sector. This may be desirable<br />

in Ireland as a means to maintain greater competition in the market, especially if<br />

recommendations made above – to introduce competition for, rather than in, the<br />

market – are implemented, since in this context, it is important to attract sufficient<br />

numbers <strong>of</strong> bidders for a given tender.<br />

On the other hand, if local authorities were removed from operations completely, one<br />

could argue that they could concentrate upon the regulatory function more effectively.<br />

It is not clear, however, that this balance – involvement in regulation, but no<br />

involvement in service delivery – sits easily with local authorities. Indeed, to the<br />

extent that local authorities are obvious bodies to take over responsibility for<br />

household waste collection in a situation where competition ‘for the market’ is<br />

102 EPA, 2007, National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme: Annual Report, available at:<br />

http://www.epa.ie/downloads/pubs/waste/prevention/final%204th%20nwpp%20annual%20report%2<br />

0to%20minister%20july%202008%2022.pdf<br />

29/09/09


introduced (and under which, they would manage tendering processes), then it might<br />

not make sense for them to be regulating at the same time.<br />

Probably a more nuanced view <strong>of</strong> the situation is required in which the regulatory<br />

functions are reconsidered in the context <strong>of</strong> the revised market structures being<br />

recommended (in respect <strong>of</strong> competition for the market).<br />

Bacon Associates, in its report for Repak, has recommended that the EPA takes over<br />

the role <strong>of</strong> monitoring compliance with the packaging regulations from the local<br />

authorities. 103 The role <strong>of</strong> local authorities in respect <strong>of</strong> implementing / enforcing<br />

producer responsibility does vary across the producer responsibility streams, and the<br />

manner <strong>of</strong> this variation does not follow an obvious logic.<br />

4.3 Recommendations<br />

The OECD notes that there is a lack <strong>of</strong> regulatory coherence in Ireland. Infrastructure<br />

investment on a private level will not, it suggests, advance at the desired pace until<br />

clarity is achieved as to the future <strong>of</strong> waste management regulation in Ireland.<br />

However, it <strong>of</strong>fers no obvious solution to the problems, specifying what Ireland might<br />

aim for in rather broad terms: 104<br />

69<br />

To establish well-functioning waste management, Ireland should implement a<br />

system that entails: 1) a regulatory regime that eliminates conflict <strong>of</strong> interest;<br />

2) lower market entry barriers by reducing lengthy procedures; 3) contractual<br />

arrangements that oblige service deliverers, whether public or private, to<br />

deliver on sustainable development objectives such as broader environmental<br />

goals and universal service; 4) a financing system that removes hidden<br />

subsidies and allows all service providers to bear the actual cost <strong>of</strong> service<br />

delivery in their fee structure (including recycling costs), in accordance with<br />

the polluter-pays-principle; and 5) planning and co-ordination arrangements<br />

that allow rational infrastructure use and investment.<br />

No one could disagree with, for example, the desirability <strong>of</strong> a regulatory regime that<br />

eliminates conflict <strong>of</strong> interest (if indeed the conflict is more than merely perceived,<br />

which the OECD implicitly – in making this recommendation - suggests that it is), or <strong>of</strong><br />

implementing contractual arrangements which aspire to universal service and<br />

broader environmental goals. The question is, rather, how to achieve that.<br />

Our view is that at least some <strong>of</strong> the regulatory tensions stem from the public sector<br />

becoming increasingly involved in shaping developments in the markets for<br />

commercial and industrial waste, and the private sector becoming increasingly<br />

involved in household waste even where (some) local authorities feel they have no<br />

right to be involved due to their being the incumbent provider. The ongoing legal<br />

103 Peter Bacon and Associates (2008) Examination <strong>of</strong> Impact <strong>of</strong> Recent Price Collapse in Markets for<br />

Recyclate Materials and Required Intervention, Report for Repak, available at:<br />

http://www.repak.ie/files/Bacon%20Report%20on%20<strong>Waste</strong>%20Markets,%20Nov.%202008_1.pdf<br />

104 OECD (2008) Ireland: Toward an Integrated Public Service, Paris: OECD, available at:<br />

http://www.oecd.org/document/31/0,3343,en_2649_33735_40529119_1_1_1_1,00.html<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


disputes (and the time taken to resolve them) highlight the fact that the law is<br />

insufficiently clear.<br />

In this context, we suggest that there is a need to strengthen the demarcation <strong>of</strong> local<br />

authority roles in respect <strong>of</strong> different waste streams. One possible reason that<br />

tensions arise in the collection market is that no one seems entirely sure (until the<br />

courts decide) who has the right to compete in which market. In addition, the local<br />

authorities’ power to direct waste appears to be being used to direct commercial<br />

waste collected by commercial collectors into facilities in which the local authorities<br />

may have a significant commercial interest. We suggest that the market needs to be<br />

clearly delineated as follows:<br />

70<br />

1. Local authorities will become responsible for (directly, or through tendering)<br />

household waste collection. They will also have responsibility for, and would<br />

choose whether to procure facilities, or capacity at existing facilities, for the<br />

treatment and disposal <strong>of</strong> the waste so collected. In other words, they would<br />

be expected to direct household waste to specific facilities. The issue<br />

regarding waivers for low-income households would effectively become one for<br />

local authorities to address in the context <strong>of</strong> their role in organising service<br />

delivery;<br />

2. A very different situation would prevail in respect <strong>of</strong> commercial waste<br />

collection. The local authority would have no powers <strong>of</strong> direction over this<br />

waste. A collection market would remain for commercial and industrial waste.<br />

The market, suitably configured (with a residual waste levy in place, alongside<br />

the EPA’s Guidance on Pre-treatment, and requirements to sort waste on the<br />

part <strong>of</strong> businesses) would be left to determine how this waste was treated. The<br />

market would also be expected to provide the relevant treatment and disposal<br />

infrastructure for the collected material.<br />

At least two areas escape this seemingly neat division:<br />

29/09/09<br />

a) Both local authorities and the private sector operate landfills. The two<br />

compete, and would do so for both household and commercial waste.<br />

They will continue to do so in future, so the issue – real or perceived –<br />

<strong>of</strong> how facilities are consented retains significance;<br />

b) Both local authorities and the private sector collect commercial waste.<br />

The two would, where the local authority was active in collection,<br />

compete in this market. There are, in this case, some issues worthy <strong>of</strong><br />

consideration. The OECD notes: 105<br />

Local authorities are not subject to value-added tax (VAT) for<br />

their waste management services as in the case for the private<br />

sector. While this is not an issue at the household level, it is an<br />

issue for commercial customers where service users cannot<br />

claim back VAT. This allows local authorities to <strong>of</strong>fer their<br />

105 OECD (2008) Ireland: Toward an Integrated Public Service, Paris: OECD, available at:<br />

http://www.oecd.org/document/31/0,3343,en_2649_33735_40529119_1_1_1_1,00.html


71<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

services 13.5% cheaper; this disadvantage for business was<br />

calculated at EUR 30 million.<br />

Local authorities are also partially subsidised for their waste<br />

management activities. Local public waste infrastructure<br />

projects (both capital and operating costs) are partly funded by<br />

the Environment Fund, to which the private sector is not eligible,<br />

though this is also to compensate, in part, for the local<br />

authorities’ recycling activities. By the end <strong>of</strong> 2005, EUR 42<br />

million <strong>of</strong> the Fund had been used to support local authority<br />

investments in waste management and recycling<br />

infrastructure.19 It is important to note that EUR 42 million<br />

relates to the total spent from the fund in 2005 and does not<br />

relate entirely to investment in waste recycling infrastructure,<br />

but also includes areas such as enforcement and awareness<br />

campaign schemes to prevent/reuse waste, etc.<br />

The most obvious way to resolve the first issue – related to landfill ownership - would<br />

be to require local authorities and the private sector to follow exactly the same<br />

process. In principle, it would be desirable also to exclude the local authorities from<br />

the process, but this is likely to prove rather difficult.<br />

The second issue – related to competition in collection – is more complex. One<br />

matter which might easily be cleared up, however, relates to the Environment Fund.<br />

We would suggest that the Environment Fund must be reconfigured such that:<br />

a) In the absence <strong>of</strong> competition (for funds), local authorities should only be a<br />

beneficiary in cases where disbursements are not used to support any activity<br />

in which the public sector and private sector are in direct competition (for<br />

example, cleaning up old landfills);<br />

b) In all cases where it is intended that the local authority may be a beneficiary,<br />

and where the private sector also provides the service under consideration,<br />

then the relevant funds should be made available to all relevant parties,<br />

preferably on a competitive basis, to ensure that disbursements deliver value<br />

for money;<br />

This ought to ensure that the revenues from the Environment Fund should not distort<br />

competition in future.<br />

With regard to VAT, the sentiment <strong>of</strong> the OECD is clear enough. We would agree with<br />

this. If players are competing in the same market, it makes little sense to give one<br />

competitor a major advantage through the VAT system. We recommend, therefore,<br />

that in the context <strong>of</strong> ongoing review <strong>of</strong> local government finance, the law in relation<br />

to the treatment <strong>of</strong> local authorities for VAT be examined. In principle, the aim should<br />

be to achieve the following:<br />

� To ensure that where commercial companies bid for tenders being let by local<br />

authorities for the provision <strong>of</strong> services to households, the cost <strong>of</strong> the services<br />

to households is affected by VAT in the same way as it would be if the service<br />

was provided by the local authority itself. Ways <strong>of</strong> doing this could include<br />

either allowing local authorities to claw back the VAT on, or exempt from VAT,<br />

the services provided to households;


72<br />

� To ensure that where commercial companies and local authorities compete<br />

directly in the market, that the two services are treated equivalently from the<br />

point <strong>of</strong> view <strong>of</strong> VAT. One way <strong>of</strong> doing this would be to require local authorities<br />

to charge VAT to customers where they engage in what is effectively the<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> a commercial service.<br />

In the absence <strong>of</strong> these changes, the rather obvious point is that local authorities, in<br />

benchmarking the value for money <strong>of</strong> their services, would effectively have a<br />

significant head start in seeking to demonstrate such value. Indeed, the<br />

consequences might be to preserve existing levels <strong>of</strong> inefficiency as long as these<br />

were not in excess <strong>of</strong> the implied level <strong>of</strong> cost advantage implied by the VAT regime.<br />

If this delineation is successfully achieved, and made explicit in legislation, one might<br />

have good reason to hope that some <strong>of</strong> the existing tensions will become less<br />

problematic. The spheres <strong>of</strong> influence will be clarified somewhat.<br />

Indeed, we doubt, if this situation were to become established, whether the current<br />

role <strong>of</strong> local authorities in issuing waste collection permits, would remain as it<br />

currently stands. The OECD was keen to highlight the potential for local authorities to<br />

make use <strong>of</strong> their licensing powers to improve the quality <strong>of</strong> service delivery:<br />

29/09/09<br />

As for local authorities, in the short-term, they should review how they could<br />

better make use <strong>of</strong> their licensing authority. As this step, however, will<br />

increase conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest under the dual responsibility model, it may be<br />

wise to transfer licensing authority to the regional or national levels in the<br />

longer-term.<br />

If, as proposed elsewhere in this review:<br />

� Ambitious targets are set for household waste management (see Main Summary<br />

Report);<br />

� Local authorities are given responsibility for household waste collection (see<br />

Annex 3.0);<br />

� Service standards are set for commercial and industrial waste collection (see<br />

Main Summary); and<br />

� Levies on residual waste management are set so as to internalise externalities<br />

and improve the management <strong>of</strong> waste (see Annex 56.0),<br />

then the key issue in terms <strong>of</strong> licensing waste collectors is likely to become one <strong>of</strong><br />

ensuring the collectors are registered and operating in line with Articles 26 and 34 <strong>of</strong><br />

the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive.<br />

As an additional point, as mentioned above, it is not clear why local authorities play<br />

different regulatory role in respect <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility for packaging to their<br />

role in other producer responsibility schemes. It may be that there are good reasons<br />

for this (the diffuse nature <strong>of</strong> the responsibility), but there might also be some<br />

inefficiencies in the regulation <strong>of</strong> these schemes, not least to the extent that the<br />

regulated parties across the different waste streams are, in some cases, one and the<br />

same entity.<br />

Finally, it is difficult to completely separate concerns regarding the role which local<br />

authorities play in the market from their role, in the regions, as developers <strong>of</strong>


statutory waste management plans. In our view, this aspect has not been explored in<br />

sufficient depth. The implications for competition <strong>of</strong> a system in which:<br />

� Regions, composed <strong>of</strong> local authorities, develop regional waste management<br />

plans;<br />

� The plans designate the required facilities; and<br />

� Alternatives to the facilities in the plan are rejected for being non-compliant with<br />

the plan<br />

are clear. In short, monopolies are de facto established, the more so if local<br />

authorities seek to use powers <strong>of</strong> direction to channel waste into a specific facility.<br />

This is not a healthy situation. The role <strong>of</strong> the regions is addressed in Annex 5.0.<br />

73<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


5.0 Governance Structures / Responsibilities for<br />

Delivery <strong>of</strong> National Strategy<br />

Ireland has 34 City and County Councils. Under the Local Government Act 1991, 8<br />

regional authorities were established. 106 These regional authorities are responsible<br />

for promoting the coordination <strong>of</strong> public service provision and monitoring the delivery<br />

<strong>of</strong> the EU Structural Fund assistance in the regions. The regional authorities carry out<br />

the following tasks:<br />

74<br />

� <strong>Review</strong>ing the development plans <strong>of</strong> the local authorities and examining the<br />

plans with consideration for the overall development needs <strong>of</strong> the region;<br />

� Preparing regional planning guidelines and regional economic/social<br />

strategies; and<br />

� Promoting cooperation and joint arrangements among the local authorities<br />

including the implications and effects <strong>of</strong> their decisions on the services for the<br />

regions.<br />

Membership <strong>of</strong> the regional authorities consists <strong>of</strong> elected <strong>of</strong>ficials from the local<br />

authorities (numbers related to the population <strong>of</strong> the local authority area). The<br />

regional authorities are the Border, the West, the Mid-West, the South-West, the<br />

Midlands, the South-East, the Mid-East, and Dublin.<br />

5.1 Regional Authorities in <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act (1996) suggested, in Article 25, that local authorities<br />

might come together to plan for waste management. In 1998, DoEHLG set out a plan<br />

to change the waste management in Ireland – ‘Changing Our Ways’. This policy<br />

statement advocated the development <strong>of</strong> regional waste management.<br />

The result <strong>of</strong> this was the formation <strong>of</strong> 7 regions, with three counties developing their<br />

own separate waste plans. These were Donegal, Wicklow and Kilkenny County<br />

Councils. The remaining 7 regions are as follows:<br />

� Cork<br />

� Connaught<br />

� Dublin<br />

� South-East<br />

� Mid-West<br />

� North-East and<br />

� Midlands.<br />

106 Irish Regions Office (2006) Regional Authorities, available at: http://www.iro.ie/irish_regions.html<br />

29/09/09


Each region has devised, and periodically revises, a separate waste management<br />

plan (Regional <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan – RWMP). These plans account for the<br />

growth in waste arisings and create a plan to process these with consideration for the<br />

waste hierarchy. The National Overview <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans proposed to<br />

consolidate the RWMPs and chart the expected waste arisings in the country,<br />

objectives in terms <strong>of</strong> recycling and infrastructure development, and the implications<br />

<strong>of</strong> change. 107<br />

The first thing that will be noticed is that the regions which have emerged for the<br />

purposes <strong>of</strong> waste management are not the same as those which were established<br />

under the Local Government Act 1991. Indeed, there appears to have been no<br />

constraint placed upon local authorities in constituting regions, and certainly no clear<br />

logic, or plan, leading to the selection <strong>of</strong> the regions as they emerged. Local<br />

authorities were neither forced to work together, nor prevented from forging their own<br />

path. Discussions with DoEHLG <strong>of</strong>ficials suggest that local authorities formed regions<br />

that appeared to make sense to them.<br />

In the document, Taking Stock and Moving Forward, DoEHLG stated:<br />

75<br />

When Changing our Ways was published in 1998, it encouraged local<br />

authorities to form regional groupings in order to secure more efficient<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> infrastructure and services. One <strong>of</strong> the main benefits arising is the<br />

resultant significant economy <strong>of</strong> scale, providing a viable framework in<br />

planning and volume terms for the development <strong>of</strong> integrated and innovative<br />

solutions and a favourable climate for the creation <strong>of</strong> beneficial partnership<br />

arrangements between local authorities and the private sector.<br />

Expected benefits <strong>of</strong> the RWMPs included the aforementioned economies <strong>of</strong> scale. In<br />

addition to these economies <strong>of</strong> scale, further benefits were expected in terms <strong>of</strong>:<br />

� Efficiency <strong>of</strong> collection services;<br />

� Beneficial partnerships between the public and private sector; and<br />

� A framework for the development <strong>of</strong> an integrated waste management<br />

approach.<br />

It was also expected that following the development <strong>of</strong> a plan, procurement processes<br />

for waste infrastructure not provided by the private sector would follow.<br />

5.1.1 Reaction to RWMPs<br />

The RWMPs had a somewhat problematic gestation. One academic commentator has<br />

a critical perspective on the changes which occurred with a view to ensuring<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the RWMPs, suggesting the move eroded local democracy: 108<br />

107 DoEHLG (2004) National Overview <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans, available at:<br />

http://www.environ.ie/en/Environment/<strong>Waste</strong>/PublicationsDocuments/FileDownLoad,1465,en.pdf<br />

108 Anna Davies (2003) <strong>Waste</strong> Wars – Public Attitudes and the Politics <strong>of</strong> Place in <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Strategies, Irish Geography, 36 (1), pp.77-92.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


76<br />

29/09/09<br />

So challenging did some local authorities find reaching agreement about<br />

incineration that by 2000 six out <strong>of</strong> 28 <strong>of</strong> them still had no plan in place.<br />

During 2001 Europe was beginning to lose patience with the lack <strong>of</strong> progress<br />

in adopting waste management plans in Ireland and the threat <strong>of</strong> being taken<br />

to the European Court <strong>of</strong> Justice had been voiced. This potential intervention<br />

from Europe created tensions between national and local government. At a<br />

national level the Government needed to move the waste plan adoption<br />

process forward in order to avoid confrontation with Europe. […]<br />

While the environmental and health issues around the various waste<br />

management strategies were still being hotly contested during 2001 the<br />

National Government was keen to resolve the deadlock over the adoption <strong>of</strong><br />

plans. Attention to scalar politics <strong>of</strong> waste management and the design <strong>of</strong><br />

appropriate structures for democracy were key to the Government’s strategy<br />

for achieving movement in the planning process. In a decisive act, which was<br />

to fuel rather than contain heated debates about democracy, the Minister for<br />

the Environment intervened in the stalemate in March 2001 when he<br />

introduced the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Amendment) Bill, 2001. Alongside the<br />

more progressive developments contained within the Bill, including an<br />

environmental levy both on plastic bags and waste sent to landfill, was the<br />

transfer <strong>of</strong> the responsibility for the adoption <strong>of</strong> waste management plans<br />

from the elected members <strong>of</strong> local authorities to local authority managers. As<br />

noted by Boyle (2001) the aim <strong>of</strong> this transfer was to remove the adoption<br />

decision from the electoral process, but by doing so it was also open to<br />

criticism for eroding fundamental aspects <strong>of</strong> local democracy. It appeared to<br />

some, particularly opposition TDs, that at this stage <strong>of</strong> the process the<br />

Minister for the Environment simply wanted plans adopted irrespective <strong>of</strong> the<br />

local appropriateness <strong>of</strong> the strategies contained within them.<br />

Following the passage <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Amendment) Act, 10 regional<br />

waste management plans were finalised.<br />

From the outset bodies such as IBEC found fault with the system for the following<br />

reasons:<br />

1) Failure to cater for commercial and industrial waste;<br />

2) An underestimation <strong>of</strong> quantity <strong>of</strong> waste generated;<br />

3) No clear implementation mechanism in place;<br />

4) Insufficient capacity planned to provide real competition;<br />

5) Lack <strong>of</strong> coordination between the 10 regional plans; and<br />

6) Flow control issues related to inter-regional movement <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

It is not clear that all these criticisms bear scrutiny, but the breadth <strong>of</strong> the criticism is<br />

<strong>of</strong> note. IBEC claims that ‘poorly co-ordinated regional planning has resulted in


uneconomic infrastructure and regional monopolies.’ 109 Forfás suggests that cost<br />

efficiency has been sacrificed for the development <strong>of</strong> regional waste management<br />

plans, but neither in the case <strong>of</strong> Forfás nor in the case <strong>of</strong> IBEC is the evidence for the<br />

statements concerning infrastructure being ‘uneconomic’, or similar, made clear. 110<br />

The OECD claims that the regional waste management planning has had an effect<br />

which is the opposite <strong>of</strong> that intended. 111 They argue that the result has been<br />

overcapacity for landfill and a slowdown in the development <strong>of</strong> infrastructure higher in<br />

the hierarchy. Again, the argument is not substantiated by clear evidence, and in any<br />

case, where infrastructure is slow to develop, then capacity for landfill would,<br />

presumably, have to be greater than would otherwise have been envisaged. In other<br />

words, the one might be a logical requirement <strong>of</strong> the other.<br />

5.2 A National <strong>Waste</strong> Board?<br />

In 2002 the DoEHLG reviewed the policy statement ‘Changing Our Ways’ and<br />

suggested several recommendations with respect to regionality. Included in these<br />

recommendations was the suggested creation <strong>of</strong> a National <strong>Waste</strong> Board which would<br />

oversee the regional plans.<br />

The National <strong>Waste</strong> Board was expected to: 112<br />

77<br />

� coordinate the national and regional waste management plans<br />

� provide advice to public bodies and the private sector<br />

� act as a consultative body in the development <strong>of</strong> EU policy change<br />

� ensure the achievement <strong>of</strong> the targets set out in the national waste strategy<br />

� monitor and evaluate best practice<br />

� undertake public consultations on developments in waste strategy and provide<br />

awareness education<br />

The review which followed the ‘Changing Our Ways’ policy statement, ‘Taking Stock<br />

and Moving Forward’, suggested that planning at the national level was unnecessary:<br />

There have been calls to consider replacing the regional approach to waste<br />

management planning with a single national waste management plan. The<br />

reality is that a very clear national policy policy framework, setting ambitious targets<br />

for radical change in our approach to waste management to be achieved over<br />

109 IBEC (2006) IBEC welcomes Government's review <strong>of</strong> waste market, available at:<br />

http://www.ibec.ie/ibec/press/presspublicationsdoclib3.nsf/wvPCICCC/2DE72CDC52A50B9780257<br />

1BF0057ADA5?OpenDocument<br />

110 Forfás (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Benchmarking Analysis and <strong>Policy</strong> Priorities, available at:<br />

http://www.forfas.ie/media/forfas080528_waste_benchmarking.pdf<br />

111 OECD (2008) Ireland: Toward an Integrated Public Service, Paris: OECD, available at:<br />

http://www.oecd.org/document/31/0,3343,en_2649_33735_40529119_1_1_1_1,00.html<br />

112 EPA (2002) Delivering Change: Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>, Wexford: EPA, available at:<br />

http://www.epa.ie/downloads/pubs/waste/plans/name,11646,en.html<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


78<br />

29/09/09<br />

the period to 2013, has been in place since 1998; this was re-affirmed in the<br />

current Government programme and is now reinforced further by this<br />

document.<br />

The replacement <strong>of</strong> regional waste management planning by a single national<br />

plan has also been advocated in terms <strong>of</strong> potential cost efficiencies and the<br />

opportunities for the provision <strong>of</strong> a smaller number <strong>of</strong> larger facilities for<br />

managing our wastes. However, such considerations have to be balanced<br />

against environmental factors, particularly the need to respect the “proximity<br />

principle” which encourages the management <strong>of</strong> waste in close proximity to<br />

the location <strong>of</strong> its production. Essentially, what must be achieved is a balance<br />

between optimising the costs and efficiencies <strong>of</strong> waste management facilities<br />

and the energy and air pollution costs <strong>of</strong> transportation, and the impacts <strong>of</strong><br />

large-scale developments on a local area.<br />

It is not evident that a national plan would bring any marked improvement in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> the delivery <strong>of</strong> services and infrastructure, or that it would <strong>of</strong>fer<br />

greater refinement or flexibility in addressing local and regional requirements.<br />

Against this background, it is considered that the focus should continue to be<br />

on implementation<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> regional waste plans, rather than effectively suspending<br />

current progress on implementation pending the completion <strong>of</strong> a national<br />

plan.<br />

However, it would appear that this view is not shared by other key stakeholders in the<br />

waste management sector. Indeed, Forfas takes an opposing view:<br />

The regionally based waste planning framework is hindering the delivery <strong>of</strong><br />

cost effective, commercially viable, sophisticated waste treatment options<br />

along the waste hierarchy as it tends to result in smaller scale facilities than<br />

would be the case if infrastructure planning was done at a national level. The<br />

regional waste management plans need to be coordinated at national level to<br />

attract investment in waste infrastructure in a way that maximises potential<br />

economies <strong>of</strong> scale, competition and enables the market to pass on the<br />

benefits to businesses and households.<br />

The EPA attributes the low level <strong>of</strong> necessary infrastructure development to the lack<br />

<strong>of</strong> national waste management plan. 113<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> contractors face considerable uncertainty in developing much needed<br />

infrastructure because there is no integrated national plan that outlines<br />

detailed waste infrastructural requirements, which in turn informs regional<br />

waste management plans. The National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy does<br />

not provide the level <strong>of</strong> detail necessary for such a national waste<br />

management plan – an integrated plan should outline not only the targets but<br />

also where, by whom and how these targets should be achieved, as well as a<br />

113 EPA (2008) Hitting Targets for Biodegradable Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong>: Ten Options for Change,<br />

Wexford: EPA, available at:<br />

http://www.epa.ie/downloads/consultation/epa_bmwoptions_discussion_2008.pdf


79<br />

programme <strong>of</strong> measures to achieve the targets. In addition overall<br />

responsibility for driving the plan must be assigned. A national plan would<br />

overcome the deficits inherent in regional waste management plans and<br />

provide clear guidance to planning <strong>of</strong>ficials and waste regulatory authorities. It<br />

would also provide clarity to investors on whether their infrastructure projects<br />

are compliant with national waste and planning policies.<br />

The EPA goes on to conclude:<br />

The absence <strong>of</strong> an integrated national waste management plan creates<br />

uncertainty for investors developing new infrastructure while regional waste<br />

management plan boundaries are potentially artificial obstacles to cost<br />

effective waste management.<br />

It suggests that the following should be considered:<br />

� A detailed national waste management plan should be developed with<br />

responsibility for delivery clearly designated.<br />

� Remove unnecessary restrictions on waste management proposals that<br />

curtail waste movements across county or regional boundaries, as these<br />

restrictions may add to the cost <strong>of</strong> waste management.<br />

Thus, it stops short <strong>of</strong> recommending that the regions should no longer take<br />

responsibility for waste planning, though to the extent that it also suggests that<br />

national guidance on site selection might also be part <strong>of</strong> a National <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plan, then the proposed National Plan would seem to fulfil many <strong>of</strong> the<br />

functions <strong>of</strong> the existing Regional <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans.<br />

Several other stakeholders consulted during the course <strong>of</strong> this exercise expressed the<br />

view that they felt that the RWMPs were ineffective. They made comments to the<br />

effect that investment was made despite, rather than because <strong>of</strong>, the RWMPs. Some<br />

felt a national plan was necessary, lamenting the fact that this was never introduced.<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the advocates <strong>of</strong> a national coordinating mechanism took the view that the<br />

RWMPs should remain, but others suggested that the RWMPs should simply be cast<br />

aside in favour <strong>of</strong> a national waste board, or waste management authority.<br />

5.3 Performance and Monitoring <strong>of</strong> Regional <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Plans<br />

The Regional <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans all set targets for recycling <strong>of</strong> different waste<br />

streams. They also set out plans for the treatment <strong>of</strong> waste. Both <strong>of</strong> these vary widely<br />

across the regions.<br />

The RWMPs are essentially intended to constitute the means to deliver these, but<br />

where local authorities have withdrawn from the provision <strong>of</strong> waste collection<br />

services, then their ‘ability to ensure’ delivery <strong>of</strong> targets is likely to be rather more<br />

limited than in those cases where they have control over the process through either<br />

collecting materials themselves, or through tendering out services. Failing this,<br />

authorities would need to be pro-active in ensuring collection permits were specified<br />

so as to ensure the collection services <strong>of</strong>fered by collectors were capable <strong>of</strong> delivering<br />

on targets.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Targets such as those in the NBWS should be reflected in the RWMPs, and in<br />

particular, given that the NBWS was completed after the revision <strong>of</strong> many RWMPs, in<br />

the Annual Implementation Reports on the RWMPs. The NBWS stated:<br />

80<br />

29/09/09<br />

Each Annual Implementation Report to be prepared by local authorities on the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan, as required under Key Point<br />

13 <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Taking Stock and Moving Forward, should<br />

record progress made in relation to the National Strategy on Biodegradable<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> over the previous year. The format to be followed in the Annual<br />

Implementation Report will be specified in a Circular letter issued to all local<br />

authorities by the DoEHLG.<br />

Circular WPPR 17/08 states: 114<br />

4.9 Annual Reports on the implementation <strong>of</strong> waste management plans<br />

should be sent to the <strong>Department</strong>. In addition, Annual Reports should also<br />

be transmitted to the EPA, so that the information can be taken fully into<br />

account by the Agency when compiling their annual National <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Reports. Annex IV provides an outline template <strong>of</strong> the format <strong>of</strong> an Annual<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan Implementation Report.<br />

DoEHLG confirms that the Annual Reports which Regions are required to prepare, and<br />

which should reflect targets in, for example, the NBWS, have been received only from<br />

Dublin, Midlands, Mid-west (Limerick, Clare and Kerry) and Connacht. A review <strong>of</strong><br />

these reports highlights the fact that the Regions have not, in general, sought to<br />

understand (for example) how much paper and card, or textiles, or organic waste is<br />

being captured in their Region. These are some <strong>of</strong> the more obviously ‘transposable’<br />

<strong>of</strong> the NBWS targets, but these have not been considered thus far by the Regions.<br />

In essence, therefore, the requirement to prepare Annual Reports does not appear to<br />

have been fulfilled. When these reports are received, it is not clear what happens to<br />

them in the sense that whether Regions are, or are not, on track to deliver against<br />

their stated plan triggers no form <strong>of</strong> sanction. Indeed, in those areas where local<br />

authorities have withdrawn from service provision, it is not clear upon whom any<br />

sanction would be made to stick. In short, no one has any specific interest or<br />

incentive to make sure that what they hope will happen will in fact materialize.<br />

5.3.1 The Proximity Principle<br />

The proximity principle is referred to occasionally in respect <strong>of</strong> regional plans. The<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive discusses proximity in Article 16:<br />

The network shall enable waste to be disposed <strong>of</strong> or waste referred to in<br />

paragraph 1 to be recovered in one <strong>of</strong> the nearest appropriate installations, by<br />

means <strong>of</strong> the most appropriate methods and technologies, in order to ensure<br />

a high level <strong>of</strong> protection for the environment and public health.<br />

114 DoEHLG (2008) National Strategy on Biodegradable waste: Implementation <strong>of</strong> Segregated “Brown<br />

Bin” Collection for Biowaste and Home Composting, Circular WPPR 17/08 to each City and County<br />

Manager, 31 July 2008.


<strong>Waste</strong> referred to in paragraph 1 is:<br />

81<br />

mixed municipal waste collected from private households, including where<br />

such collection also covers such waste from other producers, taking into<br />

account best available techniques.<br />

Proximity therefore, applies to ‘disposal’, and to ‘recovery <strong>of</strong> mixed municipal waste<br />

collected from private households’, and possibly, ‘recovery <strong>of</strong> mixed waste from other<br />

producers’. Proximity also has to account for the nature <strong>of</strong> the network <strong>of</strong> facilities<br />

available, which may be more or less dispersed, spatially.<br />

Ireland is obliged to follow the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive. However, in the context <strong>of</strong><br />

Irish waste management, the RWMPs do not so much ‘have respect to’ the proximity<br />

principle. Within Ireland, they have effectively had the ability to determine what<br />

‘proximity’ means. This raises some questions as to whether the spatial distribution <strong>of</strong><br />

facilities for disposal and recovery <strong>of</strong> mixed municipal waste from households, as<br />

envisaged in the RWMPs, is likely to be ‘right’ for Ireland.<br />

5.4 Recommendation<br />

Stakeholders have found it difficult to be entirely positive about the RWMPs. If one<br />

sets aside the criticisms leveled at the system by Davies (see above), then the<br />

RWMPs appear to have been based upon a presumption that regionalization would<br />

lead to economies <strong>of</strong> scale. The OECD recommends that waste management is best<br />

catered for at local level to reduce transaction costs. The OECD also notes that the<br />

area needed for efficient economies <strong>of</strong> scale in waste management is geographically<br />

small (circa 50,000 inhabitants). Hence, it is not clear that many <strong>of</strong> the local<br />

authorities in Ireland are <strong>of</strong> a size which is so small that such economies cannot be<br />

realized, or ‘more or less’ realized, particularly in respect <strong>of</strong> collection (where, in any<br />

case, the private sector is increasingly providing the collection service).<br />

Moving on to treatment, the presumption that RWMPs would allow economies <strong>of</strong><br />

scale to be attained, seems to have overlooked the fact that ‘competition in the<br />

market’ left no one with clear and unequivocal control over the waste stream. It is<br />

difficult to ‘scale up’ facilities and take advantages <strong>of</strong> any anticipated economies <strong>of</strong><br />

scale without control over the supply <strong>of</strong> material into a given facility. The response <strong>of</strong><br />

local authorities appears to be to seek to bridge this gap by challenging the role <strong>of</strong> the<br />

private sector in the waste collection market, and directing waste from various parties<br />

into facilities which they re involved in developing.<br />

Finally, if the intention was to ‘go after’ economies <strong>of</strong> scale in a concerted manner,<br />

then it seems anomalous that the regions vary so much in scale. The latest EPA report<br />

suggests that the smallest ‘region’ is Wicklow, managing 56 thousand tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste, whilst the majority <strong>of</strong> regions deal with 125-200 thousand tonnes<br />

<strong>of</strong> household waste, with Dublin Region dealing with 479 thousand tonnes. The<br />

variation in size seems somewhat at odds with a logic <strong>of</strong> seeking to capitalize on<br />

scale economies.<br />

The upshot is that the RWMPs appear to be able to lay claim to rather little in the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> cases at present. It is claimed that the roll out <strong>of</strong> ‘green bins’ for recycling<br />

has been a success, but it remains questionable that this change can be traced<br />

entirely to the existence <strong>of</strong> the RWMPs, rather than resulting from the actions <strong>of</strong> local<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


authorities and private companies themselves, responding to the rising savings to be<br />

made from avoided disposal (i.e. rising landfill charges – see Annex 11.0) Moreover, it<br />

is difficult to see what ‘the Regions’ really do, or indeed, what they can do to promote<br />

development. They have especially limited competences where they have withdrawn<br />

from service provision.<br />

This raises the inter-related questions:<br />

82<br />

� Is there a role for Regions?<br />

� If so, what should that be, and should the Regions be as they are currently<br />

constituted?<br />

� Is there a role for a National Board, and if so what would that be?<br />

Neither RWMPs nor any national waste management board can do anything to call<br />

forward development if:<br />

� The market (notably for collection) is as free as it is in Ireland; and<br />

� The incentives in place are not such that the market delivers the desired<br />

facilities in a timely and efficient manner.<br />

Assuming, therefore, that one shifts to a situation where local authorities have control<br />

over household waste (see Annex 3.0), then the first change which may occur is that<br />

economies <strong>of</strong> scale might become a concept which can be given greater significance<br />

as a consequence <strong>of</strong> local authorities having clear control over the household waste<br />

stream. Even here, however, it is unclear that regions need to be formed, as distinct<br />

entities, for this purpose. Rather, it may be equally reasonable to allow local<br />

authorities to come together in groupings as they see fit to collaborate on, for<br />

example, procurements <strong>of</strong> collection contracts, or treatment infrastructure.<br />

It is worth pointing out that in the European context, the Cities and Counties <strong>of</strong> Ireland<br />

are far from being ‘uniquely small’ where local authorities are concerned. In regions<br />

such as in the Flemish region <strong>of</strong> Belgium, local authorities group together in<br />

Intermunicipalities, which work together for the purpose <strong>of</strong> waste management.<br />

Responsibilities for waste management are devolved down to much smaller<br />

municipalities in countries such as Italy, and this has not hindered the development<br />

<strong>of</strong> services for treatment and collection. 115 Arguably, legislation simply has to allow for<br />

this possibility, and perhaps, facilitate it, rather than forcing it.<br />

In short, therefore, it is difficult to see why Regions need to play a major role in Irish<br />

waste management. Rather than creating additional bodies and layers <strong>of</strong><br />

Government, it will be rather more important to design the institutional architecture in<br />

the right manner, and to create the right incentives for actors within the sector, to<br />

deliver the right outcomes.<br />

115 It is worth clarifying here that ‘Italy’ is not ‘Naples’. The inevitable sc<strong>of</strong>fing that frequently<br />

accompanies the suggestion that any part <strong>of</strong> Italy might have a sensible waste management<br />

infrastructure belies the reality in which, as in many other countries, excellent performance sits<br />

alongside some less educative examples.<br />

29/09/09


It is suggested that the regions should be abolished. It is proposed that the<br />

requirement, under the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive, to prepare a waste management<br />

plan be delivered through a National Plan.<br />

We propose that the RWMPs be replaced with one national waste plan. This would<br />

require a change in the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act. We propose that the process <strong>of</strong><br />

changing the law, and developing the Plan, should be initiated as a matter <strong>of</strong> urgency<br />

as soon as a decision has been taken as to which <strong>of</strong> the policy recommendations<br />

made in the Main <strong>Review</strong> Document are to be taken forward. In the interim, whilst a<br />

National Plan is being developed around these policies, these policies would then<br />

guide the implementation <strong>of</strong> waste management at the local level in the intervening<br />

period. Planning decisions should reflect the policies being implemented.<br />

The ultimate responsibility for developing a National <strong>Waste</strong> Plan would rest with the<br />

Minister. A Ministerial Programme Board chaired by the Minister and including<br />

representatives from DoEHLG, EPA, IBEC, IWMA, Cre, CCMA, the CIF, An Taisce and<br />

environmental NGOs, would be responsible for steering the Plan. The Minister would,<br />

however, still make the executive decisions.<br />

83<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


POLICIES FOR MUNICIPAL WASTE<br />

84<br />

29/09/09


6.0 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Irish <strong>Policy</strong> on Prevention and<br />

Recycling<br />

The main policy documents relating to <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> in Ireland are:<br />

85<br />

� Changing Our Ways (1998); 116<br />

� Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong> - Delivering Change (2002); 117<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> - Taking Stock and Moving Forward (2004); 118 and<br />

� National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy (2006). 119<br />

These four <strong>Policy</strong> Documents are the drivers behind each <strong>of</strong> the policies analysed in<br />

this Report. This Annex highlights the documents’ influence on policy in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

waste prevention, and on recycling and composting / digestion.<br />

6.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention in Ireland<br />

The latest EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, states that a total <strong>of</strong> 3,397,683 tonnes<br />

<strong>of</strong> municipal waste was generated in Ireland in 2007, is an increase <strong>of</strong> 1.4% on the<br />

2006 figures. 120 The report also states that the recycling <strong>of</strong> municipal waste<br />

increased by 3.6% to an overall recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 36.5% and recycling <strong>of</strong> household<br />

waste continued to increase (by 8% in 2007) to an overall recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 26%.<br />

From Figure 6-1 below it is apparent that in the period 2002-2006, personal<br />

consumption <strong>of</strong> goods and services increased by 6%, gross domestic product (GDP)<br />

increased by 6% and there was a 2.6% increase in population. Over this period,<br />

municipal waste generation appears to have grown at a similar rate to GDP and<br />

personal consumption. There is a suggestion; therefore, that economic growth and<br />

the commensurate growth in consumption have been strong factors influencing the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> waste that is produced. Over this period, there appears to have been little,<br />

if any, decoupling effect. This suggests that, at least during this period, waste<br />

prevention policies and initiatives have not managed to exert a significant influence<br />

on waste generation.<br />

Ireland relies on material recycling facilities abroad, with just 24% <strong>of</strong> all waste<br />

recycling took place in Ireland in 2007. 121 Implementation <strong>of</strong> the Market<br />

Development Group commenced in 2008, the aim <strong>of</strong> which is to develop existing<br />

116 DoELG (1998) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Changing our Ways, September 1998.<br />

117 DoELG (2002) Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>: Delivering Change, March 2002.<br />

118 DoEHLG (2004) Taking Stock and Moving Forward, April 2004.<br />

119 DoEHLG (2006) National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy, April 2006.<br />

120 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Wexford: EPA.<br />

121 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Wexford: EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


markets for recyclables and identify new applications and markets for recyclable in<br />

Ireland. One <strong>of</strong> the key issues which the Programme will address is the need for more<br />

recycling infrastructure in Ireland in order to reduce reliance on overseas markets.<br />

Figure 6-1: Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Generation linked with GDP & Personal Consumption<br />

Source: EPA (2007) National <strong>Waste</strong> Database 2006, Johnstown Castle, Wexford: EPA<br />

Prevention means reducing the quantity and harmfulness to the environment <strong>of</strong><br />

materials and the substances contained therein. <strong>Waste</strong> prevention initiatives can<br />

therefore be successfully applied at any time in the life-cycle <strong>of</strong> a material or<br />

substance, including in the production process, the marketing, distribution, or<br />

utilisation stages, up to eventual discard at the end-<strong>of</strong>-life stage. Prevention is the<br />

most desirable method <strong>of</strong> waste management since the absence <strong>of</strong> waste totally<br />

eliminates the need for handling, transportation and treatment <strong>of</strong> discarded<br />

materials. Prevention <strong>of</strong> waste provides the highest level <strong>of</strong> environmental protection<br />

optimises the use <strong>of</strong> available resources and removes a potential source <strong>of</strong> pollution.<br />

It can bring bottom-line benefits to businesses, and to households, through avoiding<br />

wasted expenditure, and reducing the costs <strong>of</strong> waste management.<br />

The ultimate objectives <strong>of</strong> waste prevention are to achieve verifiable results in<br />

reversing current trends in waste production, stabilising waste arisings and<br />

decoupling waste generation from economic growth by maximising resource use<br />

efficiency. One definition <strong>of</strong> waste prevention used in Ireland is: 122<br />

86<br />

29/09/09<br />

“Elimination or reduction at source <strong>of</strong> materials and energy consumption,<br />

waste arisings (solid, liquid, gaseous and heat) and harmful substances.”<br />

In 2002/2003 the EPA carried out a study with a view to developing a framework for<br />

waste prevention in Ireland. This report, entitled “Assessment and Development <strong>of</strong> a<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Framework for Ireland (2001-WM-DS-1) Synthesis Report”, set out<br />

ten core building blocks which were considered to be a prerequisite for any such<br />

framework, these included:<br />

1. Commitment & leadership;<br />

122 EPA (2001) based on definition provided in the ERTDI <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme.


2. High quality data relating to waste and resources;<br />

3. The ability to measure prevention;<br />

4. The setting <strong>of</strong> realistic targets & effective targets;<br />

5. A solid foundation <strong>of</strong> instruments;<br />

6. A material management focus;<br />

7. The consideration <strong>of</strong> energy and equity issues;<br />

8. Taking a full product life-cycle approach;<br />

9. Linking and synergies with other national strategies; and<br />

10. A consideration <strong>of</strong> qualitative as well as quantitative prevention.<br />

Section 28 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act, 1996 to 2003, provides for a wide range<br />

<strong>of</strong> legislative and economic instruments to be applied in support <strong>of</strong> prevention<br />

initiatives.<br />

In order to build the framework mentioned above the EPA Report on “Assessment and<br />

Development <strong>of</strong> a <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Framework for Ireland (2001-WM-DS-1)<br />

Synthesis Report” sets out ten main specific measures which it suggested were<br />

required components for developing a waste prevention strategy. These were<br />

considered under three headings, namely, Communications/Information, Economic<br />

and Regulatory:<br />

Communications/Information<br />

Communications/Information<br />

Communications/Information<br />

1. Awareness Raising Programmes (e.g. Its Easy to Make a Difference/ Race Against<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>);<br />

2. Technical Support and Training;<br />

3. Research (research programme regarding materials and waste data acquisition);<br />

4. Green Public Procurement;<br />

Economic<br />

Economic<br />

5. Environmental Taxes and Charges (e.g. landfill and plastic bag levy);<br />

6. Extended Producer Responsibility;<br />

7. Economic Supports and Grants (e.g. EPA - Cleaner Greener Production Programme<br />

etc…);<br />

Regulatory<br />

Regulatory<br />

8. Restrictions and Bans;<br />

9. Agreements and Covenants; and<br />

10. Industrial Permits and Licenses.<br />

6.2 <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling in Ireland<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive defined recycling as “any recovery operation by which<br />

waste materials are reprocessed into products, materials or substances whether for<br />

87<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


the original or other purposes. It includes the reprocessing <strong>of</strong> organic material but<br />

does not include energy recovery and the reprocessing into materials that are to be<br />

used as fuels or for backfilling operations” 123. This Directive states that Member<br />

States shall take the necessary measures designed to achieve the following targets<br />

by 2020, “the preparing for re-use and the recycling <strong>of</strong> waste materials such as at<br />

least paper, metal, plastic and glass from households and possibly from other origins<br />

as far as these waste streams are similar to waste from households, shall be<br />

increased to a minimum <strong>of</strong> overall 50 % by weight” 124 .<br />

For household waste, recycling policy has been driven, in Ireland, by targets set out in<br />

policy document “Changing our Ways, 1998”, by producer responsibility legislation, by<br />

the landfill levy and by the requirement to implement pay by use (PBU) system<br />

(though this is not being implemented in all local authorities). The landfill levy has<br />

raised revenues which are paid into an Environmental Fund, along with funds raised<br />

from the plastic bag levy. The proceeds are used to support a range <strong>of</strong> measures,<br />

programmes and schemes to prevent or reduce waste, the operation <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

recovery activities, litter prevention, environmental partnership projects and<br />

environmental awareness, education and training. In 2007 €17,246,428 <strong>of</strong> the fund<br />

was paid to local authorities to assist in capital costs associated with the provision <strong>of</strong><br />

waste management infrastructure, while €11,914,847was paid to local authorities to<br />

assist with the operational costs <strong>of</strong> waste management. This funding has allowed a<br />

large number <strong>of</strong> recycling facilities/infrastructure to be put in place in Ireland, which<br />

has had a positive impact on recycling levels in Ireland.<br />

A key issue for Ireland is the freedom <strong>of</strong> the market for household waste collection.<br />

This freedom is most likely to be increasing the costs <strong>of</strong> waste collection to<br />

households to above levels, which might otherwise prevail. Household waste<br />

collection costs are rather high in Ireland compared with other countries, and this is<br />

unlikely to be conducive to bringing more households within the formal waste<br />

collection infrastructure. Rather, it is likely to act as an incentive for some households<br />

not to have their waste collected, with all that this may imply in terms <strong>of</strong> unauthorised<br />

waste activities including waste burning, and dumping.<br />

The situation in Ireland– where private and public sector may compete openly for<br />

custom from households (competition in Ireland is in the market and not for the<br />

market) – is almost unique in Europe. It is an awkward situation on which to base the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> sound collection systems and infrastructure precisely because<br />

recovering additional investments cannot be guaranteed in such an openly<br />

competitive market. The nature <strong>of</strong> the system becomes driven by price, and the<br />

willingness <strong>of</strong> the service providers to take on risk.<br />

Whilst the matter has recently proved the subject <strong>of</strong> controversy in Ireland, the<br />

overwhelming majority <strong>of</strong> other countries grant, effectively, either a monopoly to a<br />

123 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 1 November 2008 on<br />

waste and repealing certain Directives.<br />

124 Directive 2008/98/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 1 November 2008 on<br />

waste and repealing certain Directives.<br />

88<br />

29/09/09


company linked to the municipality (or a group there<strong>of</strong>), or a time limited monopoly to<br />

a waste contractor for household waste collection, following a competitive tendering<br />

process. This process should, where the procurement process is managed effectively,<br />

allow the collecting organization to achieve ‘economies <strong>of</strong> density’ in their logistics<br />

through increasing the number <strong>of</strong> pick-ups which are undertaken across a given area.<br />

This should, in turn, allow for reductions in cost for a given level <strong>of</strong> service.<br />

Other key issues in Ireland relate to the overall funding structure for household waste<br />

collection. In Ireland, whilst local authorities receive some funding support (for<br />

example, through the Environmental Fund), the service is funded increasingly through<br />

direct charges on users, usually a combination <strong>of</strong> a fixed and variable rate. Evidently,<br />

whilst local authorities may use their powers to require those holding collection<br />

permits to provide a given standard <strong>of</strong> service, they cannot control the price charged<br />

for such services.<br />

6.3 Key <strong>Policy</strong> Documents and their Contents<br />

6.3.1 Changing Our Ways<br />

The primary purpose <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> Statement, Changing Our Ways, was to provide a<br />

national framework within which local authorities and the waste industry could plan<br />

ahead with confidence. 125 This was the first in a series <strong>of</strong> government policy<br />

documents on the management <strong>of</strong> waste in Ireland. It endorsed an ‘integrated waste<br />

management approach’, based around the waste hierarchy as it was then<br />

understood, with the following order <strong>of</strong> preference:<br />

89<br />

� Prevention,<br />

� Minimisation,<br />

� Reuse<br />

� Recycling<br />

� Energy recovery,<br />

� Disposal.<br />

While this document contains the key quantitative targets for Irish waste<br />

management; to be achieved over a 15-year period (i.e. to 2013), with the exception<br />

<strong>of</strong> the second target (diversion <strong>of</strong> BMW from landfill, driven by the Landfill Directive),<br />

there does not appear to be any supporting rationale or evidence provided to justify<br />

the choice <strong>of</strong> these particular targets. The targets set out in Changing our Ways<br />

appear to be inconsistent with the National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy. In addition<br />

no numeric assessment <strong>of</strong> growth rates, past or projected is provided. Changing Our<br />

Ways is not prescriptive on residual waste treatment.<br />

125 DoELG (1998) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Changing our Ways, September 1998.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


6.3.1.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

Specifically in relation to waste prevention, the document is somewhat inconsistent,<br />

making one or two strong statements, but also omitting references in what might be<br />

considered key contexts. The document made reference to the statutory objective <strong>of</strong><br />

the local authorities’ waste management plans under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act.<br />

The first <strong>of</strong> these is ‘to prevent and minimise the production <strong>of</strong> waste and its harmful<br />

effects.’ However, the document also advises that where landfill capacity issues exist,<br />

these should be dealt with, in the first instance, through maximising composting and<br />

materials recovery. <strong>Waste</strong> prevention, somewhat strangely, is not mentioned in this<br />

context. In the final Section, also, in discussing ‘a preferred planning approach’,<br />

waste prevention is not mentioned.<br />

On the positive side, the document does raise the issue <strong>of</strong> charging for waste<br />

management in line with the level <strong>of</strong> use, specifically highlighting the potential<br />

incentive effect this may create:<br />

90<br />

29/09/09<br />

“As a matter <strong>of</strong> equity, and in order to directly incentivise waste reduction, the<br />

level <strong>of</strong> waste charges should vary according to usage. […]<br />

Where local authorities provide waste collection services, they should review<br />

their approach to household and commercial waste charges with a view to<br />

introducing weight related charging to the fullest extent possible. Similarly,<br />

every effort should be made to ensure that landfill gates fees are levied in<br />

relation to the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste accepted for disposal.”<br />

The document also highlights the role <strong>of</strong> local authorities in involving households in<br />

waste prevention activities. Considerable weight was, therefore, placed upon<br />

informing and educating the public:<br />

“The key to mobilising the general public to take a more responsible approach<br />

to waste, and support waste minimisation and recovery, is sustained public<br />

information and education. Local authorities that have not already done so<br />

should develop an on-going public awareness programme, aimed at<br />

generating a clear appreciation <strong>of</strong> the nature and scale <strong>of</strong> the waste problem,<br />

and providing practical guidance on the day to day choices which can be<br />

exercised by individuals and households.”<br />

6.3.1.2 <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling<br />

Changing Our Ways states that performance with regard to recovery and recycling<br />

must be substantially improved to address the requirements <strong>of</strong> Government <strong>Policy</strong>.<br />

The policy document sets out the following targets for recycling over a fifteen year<br />

timescale (i.e. by 2013):<br />

� Diverting 50% <strong>of</strong> household waste away from landfill;<br />

� Recycling <strong>of</strong> 35% <strong>of</strong> municipal waste; and<br />

� The development <strong>of</strong> waste recovery facilities employing environmentally<br />

beneficial technologies, as an alternative to landfill, including the development<br />

<strong>of</strong> composting and other feasible biological treatment facilities.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the main objectives set out in Changing Our Ways, 1998, is reducing, reliance<br />

on landfill in the short to medium term while encouraging alternative systems and


infrastructure with a high emphasis on waste recovery and recycling. This included a<br />

review <strong>of</strong> alternative waste collection systems and alternative Thermal and Biological<br />

Technologies in order to divert significant quantities <strong>of</strong> waste away form landfill.<br />

Various options were outlined in order to segregate materials for recovery purposes,<br />

including the use <strong>of</strong> multiple bins, alternate collection schedules, kerbside collection<br />

and “bring” systems (e.g. bottle banks).<br />

6.3.2 Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong> – Delivering Change<br />

The policy agenda in relation to waste took a further step forward in March 2002 with<br />

the publication <strong>of</strong> a policy statement specifically focused on waste prevention and<br />

recycling. Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>: Delivering Change set out an agenda <strong>of</strong><br />

initiatives designed to achieve progress at the top <strong>of</strong> the waste hierarchy, in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

preventing waste arising in the first place and achieving improved levels <strong>of</strong> recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste that does arise. 126 Funding to modernise Ireland’s recycling infrastructure<br />

and other initiatives such as the introduction <strong>of</strong> a landfill levy (subsequently<br />

introduced in mid-2002) and new Producer Responsibility Initiatives were among the<br />

instruments envisaged. The targets as set out in Changing Our Ways remain<br />

unchanged in “Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>”. In addition there is a stated aim <strong>of</strong><br />

recovering 50% <strong>of</strong> packaging waste by 2005 (which follows from the Packaging<br />

Directive). The policies described within this <strong>Policy</strong> document to help to achieve<br />

targets are not supported by any quantitative information as to the likely impact that<br />

the schemes will make, nor is progress towards them stated in any meaningful way.<br />

6.3.2.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

A key recommendation arising from the document was that a National <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Board would be established. However, the Board has never been set<br />

up. Even so, the document made a number <strong>of</strong> other recommendations in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

waste prevention.<br />

Specifically, it noted:<br />

91<br />

“Prevention is one <strong>of</strong> the most challenging aspects <strong>of</strong> waste management<br />

because it demands a wide range <strong>of</strong> linked initiatives, presenting a direct<br />

challenge to householders as well as commercial and industrial waste<br />

producers. Excessive waste is generated through poor product development;<br />

inefficient production or manufacturing processes, creation <strong>of</strong> disposable or<br />

short-duration goods, and unsustainable consumption patterns – for example,<br />

by purchasing excessively packaged products. Taking action to prevent waste<br />

being generated in the first place is fundamental to the overriding objective <strong>of</strong><br />

de-coupling economic growth from growth in waste arisings. […]<br />

An intensive and well structured waste prevention programme must now be<br />

put in place with the overall objective <strong>of</strong> stabilising, and in the longer term<br />

reversing, the growth in waste generation.” (Our emphasis).<br />

126 DoELG (2002) Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>: Delivering Change, March 2002.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


To this end, the document envisaged the setting up <strong>of</strong> a National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

Programme, this to be drawn up by a newly established Core Prevention Team (CPT)<br />

within the EPA. The remit <strong>of</strong> the CPT was set out as:<br />

92<br />

� “developing and prioritising programme objectives, with the goal <strong>of</strong> stabilising<br />

waste arisings and reversing current trends in waste production;<br />

� identifying the key organisations best placed (either individually or collectively)<br />

to contribute to the achievement <strong>of</strong> these objectives, and pursuing their<br />

engagement in support <strong>of</strong> the programme;<br />

� identifying and prioritising necessary actions to be initiated directly by or on<br />

behalf <strong>of</strong> the Core Prevention Team in pursuit <strong>of</strong> the programme objectives;<br />

� co-ordinating the activities <strong>of</strong> the different stakeholders;<br />

� identifying appropriate targets or performance indicators, and devising a<br />

representative methodology for the measurement <strong>of</strong> national performance in<br />

relation to waste prevention and minimisation.<br />

In implementing a progressive and ambitious Prevention Programme, the Core<br />

Prevention Team will –<br />

� advise and contribute to policy development and action in relation to waste<br />

prevention and minimisation, including the provision <strong>of</strong> advice to the Minister<br />

with regard to actions within the remit <strong>of</strong> Government which are necessary or<br />

desirable in support <strong>of</strong> improved national performance;<br />

� prioritise and target relevant activities within the industrial/commercial sector;<br />

� provide financial support for significant waste prevention initiatives;<br />

� support the establishment <strong>of</strong> local or regional <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation Clubs and<br />

Networks;<br />

� initiate or facilitate research to identify potential constraints and incentives<br />

with regard to waste prevention/minimisation initiatives;<br />

� provide advice and support on all aspects <strong>of</strong> waste prevention and<br />

minimisation to relevant stakeholders, by means <strong>of</strong><br />

29/09/09<br />

• training programmes,<br />

• the provision <strong>of</strong> help-line services, and<br />

• the publication <strong>of</strong> procedural manuals and other relevant guidance;<br />

� finance or initiate appropriate R&D and demonstration projects that can<br />

provide visible and factual evidence <strong>of</strong> the benefits <strong>of</strong> specific waste<br />

prevention and minimisation initiatives;<br />

� monitor and evaluate international developments in relation to best practice;<br />

� establish and finance a best practice programme and ensure effective<br />

dissemination <strong>of</strong> results;<br />

� monitor and evaluate waste audits and waste reduction programmes<br />

submitted on foot <strong>of</strong> statutory requirements (see paragraph 2.4.2), engage<br />

with businesses concerned to support consequent waste reduction initiatives,


93<br />

and liaise with local authorities in support <strong>of</strong> their enforcement function in this<br />

area; and<br />

� report annually on progress achieved.”<br />

Measures envisaged included the following:<br />

� Through the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act 1996, and the general obligation on<br />

waste producers to reduce waste, it was envisaged that the CPT would come<br />

forward with proposals for regulations requiring businesses to conduct waste<br />

audits and implement waste reduction programmes;<br />

� It was envisaged that promotion <strong>of</strong> re-use could occur through, inter alia, use<br />

<strong>of</strong> economic instruments and producer responsibility obligations;<br />

� Regarding packaging, the document noted:<br />

“The obligations arising from the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Packaging<br />

Directive, and other proposed initiatives such as mandatory waste audits,<br />

will encourage business to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> packaging which it<br />

places on the market. Mandatory re-use systems will be considered in<br />

appropriate circumstances in order to ensure that the requirements under<br />

the Packaging Directive are fulfilled.”<br />

� On non-packaging materials, it suggested that re-use could be encouraged:<br />

“through educating the public in relation to the range <strong>of</strong> products which<br />

can be re-used and also regarding the operation <strong>of</strong> those organisations<br />

which accept products for re-use and resale. Individual consumers can<br />

maximise the re-use <strong>of</strong> materials in their daily lives by adopting a few<br />

simple techniques:<br />

• use <strong>of</strong> a reusable shopping bag in preference to a disposable one;<br />

• use <strong>of</strong> resalable containers for food in preference to disposable<br />

wrappings;<br />

• use <strong>of</strong> rechargeable batteries;<br />

• servicing and repair <strong>of</strong> household equipment in preference to the<br />

purchase <strong>of</strong> new equipment; and<br />

• avoidance <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> disposable products e.g. cups, plates, cutlery,<br />

razors, cameras.<br />

The National <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board will be asked to advise on what<br />

practical measures can be taken to encourage further the re-use <strong>of</strong> nonpackaged<br />

products.”<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> exchanges were also highlighted as an approach to enhance re-use;<br />

� Charity shops were also the subject <strong>of</strong> some discussion;<br />

� The re-use <strong>of</strong> IT was identified as an approach, which could generate social<br />

benefits.<br />

These measures are all <strong>of</strong> interest, though in terms <strong>of</strong> concrete policies, as defined in<br />

this work, the first four bulleted measures above are <strong>of</strong> greatest interest.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The EPA has published a new Prevention Plan 2009-2012, this document is<br />

presented as a framework statement <strong>of</strong> intent for work to be completed on the<br />

Prevention Programme for the four-year period to 2012, subject to resources being<br />

available.<br />

6.3.2.2 <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling<br />

Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>: Delivering Change identified the main constraints on<br />

recycling activity historically in Ireland which included the readily availability <strong>of</strong> cheap<br />

landfills, a perception <strong>of</strong> the inconvenience <strong>of</strong> recycling, undeveloped and fluctuating<br />

markets for recyclables, absence <strong>of</strong> an adequate charging system and the lack <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling and reprocessing facilities. These constraints outlined in 2002 are similar to<br />

what is being experienced today; currently the main barriers include the lack <strong>of</strong> stable<br />

and economically attractive markets and outlets for recyclable materials, the lack <strong>of</strong><br />

development and roll out <strong>of</strong> source separation and segregated collection systems.<br />

In this policy document, educational and awareness initiatives were identified as<br />

being an important element to encourage the use <strong>of</strong> recycled products in Ireland. The<br />

policy statement called for the establishment <strong>of</strong> a Market Development Group to<br />

progress the existing work on market development and to expand market<br />

development initiatives for recycled products on an all island basis which would be<br />

co-ordinated through the North / South Ministerial Council. This Market Development<br />

Group (MDG) was established by the DoEHLG in July 2004, however its Programme<br />

was not <strong>of</strong>ficially launched until the end <strong>of</strong> October 2008. It was tasked with<br />

promoting the development <strong>of</strong> markets for recycled materials. The Market<br />

Development Programme aims to fully harness existing outlets in addition to<br />

identifying and developing new, reliable and stable markets for recycled materials in<br />

Ireland. The overarching Programmes will include green procurement, recycling<br />

feasibility and demonstration projects and research and development projects. The<br />

main waste streams that <strong>of</strong>fer the greatest potential for recycling in Ireland include<br />

organics, plastic and paper.<br />

Over three million tonnes <strong>of</strong> municipal waste are generated annually in Ireland. The<br />

national recovery rate for household waste reached 36.5% in 2007. Most regions<br />

plan to achieve a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 40% - 6-% in the coming decade, which will lead to<br />

an increase in the volume <strong>of</strong> recyclable materials available from the domestic waste<br />

stream. While a doubling <strong>of</strong> the recycling rate is forecast for commercial and<br />

industrial waste. Currently the majority <strong>of</strong> waste collected in Ireland for recycling is<br />

exported for reprocessing.<br />

The main goals <strong>of</strong> the Market Development Group are:<br />

94<br />

� Promote Sustainable and Indigenous Recycling Technologies;<br />

� Stimulate Growth in Recycled Products;<br />

� Develop Markets for Recycled Materials;<br />

� Stimulate Demand for Recycled Materials; and<br />

� Increase in Recycling Rates.<br />

29/09/09


To date the Market Development Group has developed its Business Plan, which<br />

details the activities the Market Development Group will undertake over the following<br />

year(s). Specific deliverables are set out in the Action Plan for 2009. 127<br />

The Action Group on the Recyclate Market was established in November 2008 by the<br />

Minister following a dramatic fall in the international price for ‘recyclates’. The drop in<br />

demand was very rapid and was caused by the current international economic<br />

situation, combined with the very large fall in oil prices. Ireland exports 85% <strong>of</strong> its<br />

recycling material, and the price fall has led to serious difficulties within the recycling<br />

industry in Ireland. The Action Group met on the 6 th <strong>of</strong> November and the following<br />

synopsis <strong>of</strong> their findings was provided:<br />

95<br />

� All agreed that storage <strong>of</strong> materials (which had commenced as a means to<br />

deal with material for which no market could be found) was only a short term<br />

solution;<br />

� Anecdotal evidence suggested that some small operators were ceasing<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> recycling bins and requesting their customers to use the ‘black<br />

bin’ (for residual waste) only;<br />

� Industry / local authorities indicated that the additional costs associated with<br />

recycling would have to be passed to households and businesses. Awareness<br />

would have to be raised among the public <strong>of</strong> the costs associated with<br />

recycling.<br />

� All agreed that high quality material was required for access to the key<br />

Chinese market (to which much <strong>of</strong> Ireland’s collected paper and card is sent,<br />

sometimes via the UK), and that this had implications for some operators’<br />

current collection and treatment systems;<br />

� Some members <strong>of</strong> the industry said movement on the landfill levy was urgently<br />

required in order to ensure that recycling efforts are not undermined and to<br />

remove any future temptation to landfill such material;<br />

� Both industry and the EPA recommended co-firing (at, for example, cement<br />

kilns) be considered for some <strong>of</strong> the material; and<br />

� Infrastructure and indigenous recycling industry need to be developed.<br />

Other initiatives such as the development <strong>of</strong> the National Strategy on Biodegradable<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> (published in 2006) and a National Compost Standard were also identified in<br />

this <strong>Policy</strong> document as being important projects to undertake to further develop<br />

markets for recycled products in Ireland. 128<br />

127 DoEHLG (2009) Market Development Programme for <strong>Waste</strong> Resources, Action Plan 2009,<br />

http://www.mdg.ie/MDGUploadedFiles/file/MDP%20Action%20Plan_8_06_09.pdf<br />

128 DoEHLG (2007) Market Development Programme for <strong>Waste</strong> Resources 2007-2011.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


6.3.3 <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> – Taking Stock and Moving Forward<br />

In April 2004, the Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government<br />

published the National Overview <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans and <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong>: Taking Stock and Moving Forward. 129 The report involved an overview<br />

<strong>of</strong> progress from 1998 to 2003 and a strategy for progress into the future. Relative to<br />

the previous policy statements, the document appears to have a reduced emphasis<br />

on waste prevention. The emphasis is very much on ‘management’ <strong>of</strong> waste that is<br />

generated.<br />

The report noted that waste growth was proving to be greater than had been<br />

anticipated:<br />

96<br />

29/09/09<br />

“From a waste management planning perspective, the significance <strong>of</strong> the data<br />

centres on the fact that municipal waste arisings in 2001, at about 2.7 million<br />

tonnes, had already exceeded the medium term projections in waste<br />

management plans. In the context <strong>of</strong> projections <strong>of</strong> possible future waste<br />

arisings, local authorities should have regard to the possible scenarios<br />

identified by the EPA in the National <strong>Waste</strong> Database Report 2001.”<br />

Elsewhere, we have commented on the fact the scenarios referred to in the EPA<br />

National <strong>Waste</strong> Database Report 2001 are hardly definitive, with one positing a slight<br />

decline in waste over 14 years (2001-2015), and another implying a near-quadrupling<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste over the same period (with five other scenarios in between - the projections<br />

are shown in Figure 1-2 below). 130 The report recognises that a key aim <strong>of</strong> the Core<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Team within the EPA ‘will be to improve data on waste arisings so<br />

that a sound basis for the measurement and monitoring <strong>of</strong> the Programme’s impact<br />

can be established.’<br />

129 DoEHLG (2004) Taking Stock and Moving Forward, April 2004.<br />

130 See Eunomia with Tobin (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Planning and Regulation in Ireland, Report for<br />

Greenstar.


Table 6-1: Generation <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Projected to 2015, tonnes<br />

Source: EPA (2003) National <strong>Waste</strong> Database Report 2001, Johnstown Castle, Co. Wexford: EPA.<br />

6.3.3.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

The document itself noted that progress in recycling had been made, but less<br />

progress had been made at other tiers in the waste hierarchy:<br />

97<br />

“In particular, while good progress has been made in relation to recycling,<br />

there is a need to secure greater advances on activities higher higher in the<br />

hierarchy - in relation to waste waste waste prevention prevention and and minimisation minimisation - as well as those<br />

at the lower levels - in terms <strong>of</strong> thermal thermal treatment treatment treatment and and residual residual landfill. landfill.” landfill.<br />

This <strong>Policy</strong> document states that waste prevention initiatives are crucial in order to<br />

effectively decouple waste generation from economic growth. It states that “It<br />

therefore remains true that, although waste prevention has been the paramount<br />

objective <strong>of</strong> both national and Community waste management policies for many<br />

years, limited progress has been made so far to turn the objective <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

prevention into practice.”<br />

The report announced the launch, with immediate effect, <strong>of</strong> the National <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Prevention Programme, which had been proposed in the previous policy document. As<br />

had been envisaged, the Programme was to be led by a Core Prevention Team within<br />

the Environmental Protection Agency, the work being supported with €2million in<br />

start-up funding from the Environment Fund. However, the National <strong>Waste</strong> Board had<br />

disappeared from view.<br />

6.3.3.2 <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling<br />

This <strong>Policy</strong> document states that progress has been achieved in recycling since the<br />

publication <strong>of</strong> “Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>: Delivering Change, 2002”; however<br />

close attention must be paid to the development <strong>of</strong> markets for recyclable materials.<br />

The <strong>Policy</strong> document stated four key areas have to be addressed if Ireland’ recycling<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


performance is to be radically improved, these include, better separation and sorting<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste at source, provision <strong>of</strong> an adequate infrastructure for the collection and<br />

management <strong>of</strong> waste arisings, greater reprocessing capacity to convert waste into<br />

usable products or raw materials and the generation <strong>of</strong> markets and improved<br />

demand for recycled or recyclable materials, especially in the manufacturing and<br />

construction sectors.<br />

On pay-by-use charging, the document set out a date by which it expected the<br />

completion, nationally, <strong>of</strong> the switch to weight/volume based charging. It envisaged<br />

that responsibility for doing so would rest with individual collectors, with local<br />

authorities including appropriate conditions in waste collection permits, the first twoyearly<br />

reviews <strong>of</strong> which were then starting to fall due.<br />

6.3.4 National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy<br />

The National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy (NBWS) states that its most desirable<br />

option is waste prevention or reduction <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste production,<br />

to minimise the amount <strong>of</strong> waste requiring collection and treatment. The next most<br />

desirable option is reusing biodegradable municipal waste (BMW), such as cardboard<br />

and textiles. This strategy provides a combination <strong>of</strong> measures based on education /<br />

awareness and economic instruments aimed at reducing BMW generation. For<br />

biodegradable waste that must be collected and managed, materials recycling and<br />

biological treatment are favoured, since they recover the material for new beneficial<br />

uses.<br />

6.3.4.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

The National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy (NBWS) includes ambitious targets for<br />

the prevention <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste. It is not clear, however, who is to be charged<br />

with implementing these, other than the EPA through its waste prevention<br />

programme.<br />

Elsewhere, we have commented on the significant change in tone and substance<br />

between the Draft and the Final Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy. 131 The draft strategy,<br />

published in 2004, applied an annual growth rate <strong>of</strong> 3.8% to the arisings <strong>of</strong><br />

biodegradable municipal waste. This was the growth rate experienced from 1995-<br />

1998 as reported in the EPA Report <strong>of</strong> 2001. The logic was presented as follows:<br />

98<br />

29/09/09<br />

“A waste growth rate <strong>of</strong> 3.8% per annum has been applied for the period <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Strategy. This is the growth rate that was experienced in the period 1995-1998.<br />

While economic growth and population growth may moderate in the coming<br />

years, choosing a relatively high growth rate such as this means the strategy<br />

should prescribe adequate waste recovery capacity and in any case there will<br />

be no difficulty if the landfill diversion targets are ultimately exceeded.” 132 (our<br />

emphasis)<br />

131 Eunomia with Tobin (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Planning and Regulation in Ireland, Report for Greenstar.<br />

132 DOEHLG (2004) Draft National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy. 2004


No adjustment was made to the projected growth rate to allow for the impact <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

prevention activities. The report stated that:<br />

99<br />

“Figures record that biodegradable municipal waste generation has increased<br />

by about 50% in that 9-year period [1995-2004], with 1.935 million tonnes<br />

generated in 2004.” 133<br />

The Final NBWS discusses, in Section 3.2, waste growth rates. Although the approach<br />

taken seems far from transparent, growth rates appear to have been based on work<br />

undertaken in 2004 (apparently, at the same time as the Draft Strategy was being<br />

developed). 134 In relation to historical growth rates the Final NBS states that:<br />

It adds that:<br />

“There have been anecdotal reports <strong>of</strong> appreciable reductions in the amount<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste presented since the introduction <strong>of</strong> the ‘Pay-by-Use’ (PBU) system on<br />

1 st January 2005.”<br />

“Significant results are anticipated from the implementation <strong>of</strong> the National<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme – combined with the awareness/ education<br />

campaigns, the application <strong>of</strong> Pay-By-Use systems <strong>of</strong> waste charges and other<br />

ancillary waste prevention activities - over the duration <strong>of</strong> the Strategy.”<br />

Reductions in biodegradable waste were forecast as follows (being essentially a<br />

reduction in the trend in arisings):<br />

� 2005 to 2007 3% reduction factor each year<br />

� 2008 to 2010 4% reduction factor each year<br />

� 2011 to 2013 5% reduction factor each year<br />

� 2014 to 2016 6% reduction factor each year<br />

As regards future waste arisings, the EPA-led National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme<br />

was forecast, in the Final NBWS, to be the prime mechanism for achieving reductions<br />

in biodegradable waste, along with ‘related initiatives’. 135 As discussed elsewhere,<br />

there appears to have been little or no attempt to model exactly which measures<br />

would contribute what level <strong>of</strong> reduction, and hence, contribution to the reduction<br />

targets set. 136<br />

Targets were set for home composting, the aim being to ensure this takes place at<br />

20% <strong>of</strong> urban households and 55% <strong>of</strong> rural households – equivalent to some 35% <strong>of</strong><br />

all households - by 2010. It was anticipated that potential yield from this would be<br />

between 10% to 12% <strong>of</strong> available organic waste in the years 2010 and 2016.<br />

133 DOEHLG (2004) Draft National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy. 2004<br />

134 DOEHLG (2004) National Overview <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans, April 2004.<br />

135 DoEHLG (2006) National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy, 2006.<br />

136 Eunomia with Tobin (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Planning and Regulation in Ireland, Report for Greenstar.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


6.3.4.2 <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling<br />

The Strategy states that source separation is the key to maximizing recycling. The<br />

Strategy details recycling rates for paper and cardboard in order to meet the overall<br />

landfill diversion targets for BMW. It states that a combination <strong>of</strong> kerbside collection<br />

and centralised reception facilities (Recycling Centres and Bring Centres) will be<br />

employed to achieve these. They are set in terms <strong>of</strong> the capture <strong>of</strong> paper and<br />

cardboard:<br />

100<br />

� 45% for households and 61% for commerce in 2010, corresponding to 55% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW;<br />

� 55% for households and 71% for commerce in 2013, corresponding to 65% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW; and<br />

� 60% for households and 73% for commerce in 2016, corresponding to 67% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW.<br />

In relation to recovery infrastructure, the Strategy states that there is a requirement to<br />

expand the existing Materials Recovery Facility (MRF) capacity in all regions to accept,<br />

separate, grade and bale various paper grades and can do so in parallel with recovery<br />

<strong>of</strong> other wastes such as packaging.<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> recovered paper and cardboard in Ireland is exported (mainly to the<br />

UK) into an international market for waste paper. The Strategy states that<br />

mechanisms which will lead to a rapid expansion in recycling include promotion <strong>of</strong><br />

separate collections, restricting disposal outlets, restricting illegal activities,<br />

developing markets and producer responsibility mechanisms.<br />

For organic waste, the targets were:<br />

� 40% coverage for households and 60% coverage for commerce in 2010 at an<br />

estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 45% to 60% respectively, corresponding to 25% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall organic waste generation within BMW;<br />

� 45% coverage for households and 70% coverage for commerce in 2013 at an<br />

estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 50% to 65% respectively, corresponding to 33% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall organic waste generation within BMW; and<br />

� 50% coverage for households and 70% coverage for commerce in 2016 at an<br />

estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 55% to 70% respectively, corresponding to 36% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall organic waste generation within BMW.<br />

The NBWS also includes proposals for regulations banning the following materials<br />

from mixed collection and landfill:<br />

� Office Paper 2006<br />

� Green <strong>Waste</strong> 2007<br />

� Food <strong>Waste</strong> 2008<br />

The NBWS also proposed that producer responsibility initiatives for the following<br />

materials should be developed;<br />

� Newspaper and magazines; and<br />

� Telephone directories,<br />

29/09/09


whilst initiatives for unsolicited mail and textiles were also mooted.<br />

Finally, a Strategy Implementation Group was to be established to co-ordinate the<br />

Strategy’s implementation.<br />

6.4 Summary<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> statements on waste management have blown somewhat ‘hot and cold’ where<br />

waste prevention and recycling policy measures have been considered.<br />

6.4.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

In the national documents, the following policies (or consideration there<strong>of</strong>) relating to<br />

waste prevention have been mentioned (and we indicate where they have been<br />

implemented):<br />

101<br />

� Requiring businesses to conduct waste audits and implement waste reduction<br />

programmes (not implemented);<br />

� Promotion <strong>of</strong> re-use <strong>of</strong> non-packaging materials through, inter alia, use <strong>of</strong><br />

economic instruments and producer responsibility obligations (not<br />

implemented);<br />

� Mandatory re-use systems for packaging to be considered in appropriate<br />

circumstances in order to ensure that the requirements under the Packaging<br />

Directive are fulfilled (not implemented); and<br />

� On non-packaging materials, National <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board to advise on<br />

what practical measures can be taken to further encourage the re-use <strong>of</strong> nonpackaged<br />

products (not implemented, National <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board<br />

never established).<br />

In addition, the following were mentioned:<br />

� Establish a National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme (implemented);<br />

� Education / provision <strong>of</strong> information (implemented);<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> exchanges were also highlighted as an approach to enhance re-use<br />

(implemented locally);<br />

� A target for home composting to be carried out at 35% <strong>of</strong> all households<br />

(mentioned but not actively pursued);<br />

� Charity shops were also the subject <strong>of</strong> some discussion (already in existence);<br />

and<br />

� Develop guidance on refurbishment and re-use <strong>of</strong> IT equipment, including<br />

computers (in place).<br />

The Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy expects great things from the National <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Prevention Programme, but little information was provided to indicate how it was<br />

expected that this would generate the significant reductions in biodegradable<br />

municipal waste, relative to trend, envisaged in the document.<br />

A review <strong>of</strong> various policies and initiatives that have influenced household and nonhousehold<br />

waste prevention can be found in other Annexes to the <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Review</strong>. It<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


should be noted that in the case <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> the policies outlined, waste prevention<br />

may not have been the primary objective, but nevertheless several <strong>of</strong> the policies<br />

outlined have influenced, at the margin (and could be designed to influence more),<br />

household and non household waste prevention and hence the reason for their<br />

inclusion.<br />

6.4.2 <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling<br />

With respect to recycling, the following policies are highlighted in the national policy<br />

documents (a number <strong>of</strong> policies mentioned above under waste prevention relate to<br />

recycling also):<br />

102<br />

� Pay-by-use (implemented, although the policy <strong>of</strong> universal application has<br />

probably not been fulfilled. In addition, many households do not avail<br />

themselves <strong>of</strong> any collection service);<br />

� Landfill levy (implemented, although charge levels remain low; see Annex<br />

11.0);<br />

� WEEE Regulations came into effect in Ireland in August 2005. Data from the<br />

National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007 suggests that in 2007 Ireland exceeded the<br />

recovery targets with the exception <strong>of</strong> the category “large household<br />

appliances” (77% versus 80%);<br />

� ELV Regulations came into effect in Ireland in June 2006. A supplementary<br />

fact sheet to the National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007 containing this information will<br />

be published in April 2009. The EPA is also currently compiling the Annual<br />

Report 2007 on end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles. This is due to be published in June 2009;<br />

� Batteries Regulations came into effect in Ireland in September 2008. As this is<br />

a new policy, analysis <strong>of</strong> the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> this policy will not commence<br />

until end February 2009;<br />

� Establishment <strong>of</strong> a Market Development Group (MDG) tasked with promoting<br />

the development <strong>of</strong> markets for recycled materials. The Market Development<br />

Programme aim is to fully harness existing outlets in addition to identifying and<br />

developing new, reliable and stable markets for recycled materials in Ireland.<br />

(implemented by the DoEHLG in July 2004);<br />

� Segregated Collection <strong>of</strong> Organic <strong>Waste</strong> (implemented in July 2008 via a<br />

Circular to all City and County Managers, though this has not as yet been rolled<br />

out in all local authorities);<br />

� Producer responsibility initiatives for newspaper and magazines, telephone<br />

directories, textiles and unsolicited mail (not implemented);<br />

� A ban on following materials from mixed collection and landfill (not<br />

implemented, though the Pre-treatment Guidelines <strong>of</strong> the EPA will lead to a<br />

ban, in due course, on the landfilling <strong>of</strong> untreated residual waste).<br />

29/09/09


7.0 Pay-By-Use - Ireland<br />

7.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Pay-By-Use (PBU) charging for domestic waste collection was first outlined in a policy<br />

context in a Circular Letter from the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and<br />

Local Government (DoEHLG) in 2004, Circular WIR/09/04, sent to all Directors <strong>of</strong><br />

Service in all local authorities. 137 The Circular letter gave substance to the Minister’s<br />

announcement <strong>of</strong> 2004. The Circular refers to the Minister’s announcement,<br />

103<br />

“Made last March (2004), in which he set 1 January 2005 as the date for the<br />

completion, nationally, <strong>of</strong> the changeover to the weight or volume based<br />

charging systems for the collection <strong>of</strong> waste.”<br />

It goes on to say:<br />

“In order to get a firm indication on developments, I would appreciate if you<br />

would forward a note indicating progress made to date on achieving the 1 Jan<br />

target, and the expected position at 1 January 2005 in so far as collectors in<br />

your functional area <strong>of</strong> responsibility are concerned”<br />

“Where a final pay-by-use service is not likely to be in place by 1 January<br />

2005, it is important that an interim solution be in place by that deadline.<br />

Where this is the case, please give details <strong>of</strong> the interim solution and indicate<br />

the likely date for final implementation <strong>of</strong> the service”.<br />

Circular WIR/09/04 indicates that Local Authorities are expected to have received<br />

information for their functional area on the ways in which PBU would be implemented<br />

from all waste collectors.<br />

In addition to the deadline set for the introduction <strong>of</strong> PBU ordered by the Minister and<br />

in the Circular, legislation was introduced in 2007 with regard to charging for the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> household waste collection. The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Collection Permit)<br />

Regulations, 2007 (SI No. 820 <strong>of</strong> 2007), do not specifically mention pay by use<br />

systems in terms <strong>of</strong> volume based or weight based collection charging, but refer more<br />

generally to the ‘polluter pays principle’. Sub-article 20 (2), part (h) states:<br />

“Notwithstanding the provisions <strong>of</strong> sub-article (1), the nominated authority<br />

shall attach to each waste collection permit granted by it, conditions requiring<br />

the permit holder to” – (h) “apply charges for household waste collection with<br />

respect to the polluter pays principle”.<br />

It may be noted that Sub-article 20 (3), part (c) states:<br />

“The nominated authority may attach to each collection permit that may be<br />

granted by it” – (c) “conditions to encourage sound environmental<br />

137 Circular WIR/09/04 RE: Weight/Volume related <strong>Waste</strong> Charging sent to the Director <strong>of</strong> Services in<br />

all local authorities on the 11 Sep 2004.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


104<br />

29/09/09<br />

management <strong>of</strong> waste and in particular to encourage waste prevention, reuse,<br />

recycling and recovery as set out in, but not limited to, those conditions in<br />

section 34(7) <strong>of</strong> the Act”<br />

The instruction in the circular suggests that customers can no longer be charged a<br />

flat rate for waste collection services. Instead, customers will pay by volume or weight<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste placed out for collection. An EPA report reviewing PBU domestic waste<br />

charging in Ireland, identified and defines three types <strong>of</strong> charging systems in use in<br />

Ireland: volume-based systems, tag-based systems and weight-based systems: 138<br />

� Volume-based systems require householders to subscribe to a weekly bin<br />

collection, for which they pay an annual charge. This system is considered PBU<br />

as householders can select the size <strong>of</strong> bin they subscribe to; the annual<br />

charge is based on the volume <strong>of</strong> the bin, with larger bins incurring a higher<br />

annual charge;<br />

� Tag-based systems include both tag-a-bag and tag-a-bin. These involve<br />

householders purchasing tags to attach to their bag or bin with collectors<br />

picking up only those bags and bins with the appropriate tag attached. The<br />

system is considered PBU as householders only pay for waste collection when<br />

they place bags or bins out for collection. In effect, this implies charging on the<br />

basis <strong>of</strong> frequency;<br />

� Weight-based systems involve householders paying per kilogram <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

placed out for collection. The waste collector weighs the bin and bills the<br />

householder based on this weight.<br />

Some charges are implemented on the basis <strong>of</strong> a combination <strong>of</strong> these systems, e.g.<br />

both based on volume and on weight.<br />

In addition to setting the collection fee based on more than one system above, some<br />

collectors also introduced a standing charge (usually an annual standing charge),<br />

which was payable as a partial element <strong>of</strong> the total fee structure, in addition to any<br />

variable element. Schemes vary between local authorities but commonly under a PBU<br />

charging system eligible householders are not required to pay a set standing charge<br />

for waste collection, and instead are only charged based on the volume/weight <strong>of</strong><br />

waste they present for collection. 139 Although all waste collectors, both public and<br />

private, were given the deadline <strong>of</strong> 1st January 2005, by which to implement the pay<br />

by volume/weight charging, not all collectors introduced the revised charging<br />

structure, and some continued to levy only a flat rate charge after that date.<br />

138 A. O Callaghan-Platt and A. Davies (2007) A Nationwide <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Pay-By-Use Domestic <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Charges in Ireland, Interim Report to the EPA.<br />

139 EPA (2008) A Nationwide <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Pay-By-Use (PBU) Domestic <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges in<br />

Ireland, Strive Report Series 9.


One <strong>of</strong> the waste management commitments in the Programme for Government is to<br />

ensure that ‘flat rates on waste disposal will be abolished and a mandatory system <strong>of</strong><br />

weight-related charges for waste collection introduced.’ 140<br />

7.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

PBU domestic waste pricing charges households per unit <strong>of</strong> waste placed out for<br />

waste collection. A kilogram <strong>of</strong> waste, a bag <strong>of</strong> waste and a bin <strong>of</strong> waste, for example,<br />

can all be considered a unit for waste charging purposes. PBU charges were deemed<br />

appropriate by the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage and Local Government<br />

(DoEHLG) as a means to implement the ‘polluter-pays principle’ in the waste<br />

management sector.<br />

The decision to introduce PBU domestic waste charges was made on the back <strong>of</strong> a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> key waste policy documents released by the <strong>Department</strong> (see Annex<br />

6.3.1.1). PBU charges were selected for implementation as a route to reducing<br />

Ireland’s dependence on landfill and increasing Ireland’s recycling rates to reach the<br />

national target for 2013.<br />

Such charges give the public a financial incentive to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

produced and presented for collection and disposal. In theory, PBU charges send a<br />

more accurate pricing signal for generation <strong>of</strong> refuse and therefore encourage<br />

householders to reduce waste, recycle more and change waste management<br />

habits. 141<br />

7.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The policy context, as mentioned in the section above, means that even prior to the<br />

Ministerial Circular and the 2007 <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Permit Regulations, charging for<br />

waste collection to householders had been gradually becoming more widespread:<br />

In 2004, the deadline for the implementation was set out in Circular WIR/0904, ‘for<br />

the completion <strong>of</strong> the changeover to weight or volume based charging systems was<br />

set as 1st January 2005’. Given that recent research suggests that the changeover is<br />

still incomplete, this indicates a lack <strong>of</strong> monitoring and enforcement <strong>of</strong> the expected<br />

change.<br />

140 EPA (2008) A Nationwide <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Pay-By-Use (PBU) Domestic <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges in<br />

Ireland, Strive Report Series 9<br />

141 D.V. Nestor and M.J. Podolsky (1998) Assessing incentive based environmental policies for<br />

reducing household waste disposal. Contemporary Economic <strong>Policy</strong> 16(4): 401-411; V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, P.<br />

Kooreman, M. Allers, and D. Wiersma (2001) Weight-based pricing in the collection <strong>of</strong> household waste<br />

the Oostzaan case. Resource and Energy Economics 23 (4) 359-371.<br />

105<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


7.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The DoEHLG is responsible for the overall policy context set out in the documents<br />

published since 1997. The DoEHLG and the Minister for the Environment were the<br />

bodies, which instituted the change across the board in 2004.<br />

As mentioned above the DoEHLG and the Minister take an overall position <strong>of</strong><br />

guidance in the area <strong>of</strong> the management <strong>of</strong> household waste. On-going circulars are<br />

issued to Local Authorities, and via Local Authorities to private waste collectors.<br />

Local Authorities are responsible for the issuing <strong>of</strong> waste collection permits within<br />

their administrative area, under the waste management regulatory framework. In<br />

2001, two statutory instruments were introduced regulating the issuing <strong>of</strong> collection<br />

permits for waste management operators, these being the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

(Collection Permit) Regulations, 2001 (SI No. 402 <strong>of</strong> 2001) and the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Collection Permit) (Amendment) Regulations, 2001 (SI No. 540 <strong>of</strong><br />

2001). The 2001 Regulations were revoked and superseded by the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Collection Permit) Regulations, 2007 (SI No. 820 <strong>of</strong> 2007) and the<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Collection Permit) (Amendment) Regulations, 2007 (SI No. 87<strong>of</strong><br />

2008).<br />

Domestic waste collection across Ireland is provided by a variety <strong>of</strong> methods, namely:<br />

106<br />

� Exclusively by the local authority;<br />

� Exclusively private waste collection companies; and<br />

� A combination <strong>of</strong> local authority and private waste collection companies.<br />

Hence, Local Authorities and private waste operators are involved in the collection <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste and, therefore, in the charging <strong>of</strong> collection fees to customers.<br />

It may be noted that the fee structure charged by either Local Authorities or private<br />

operators is currently not regulated (a variety <strong>of</strong> charging methods exist). This is<br />

described further in the section on implementation costs. Therefore, the Local<br />

Authorities (or indeed any other bodies) are not specifically involved in confirming that<br />

customers are being charged, or that the level <strong>of</strong> cost recovery from the charge levied<br />

encapsulates the environmental costs.<br />

The experience <strong>of</strong> Cork County Council in attempting to enforce variable changing in<br />

the county, as identified in the Fehily Timoney report referenced in Section 7.5.1 <strong>of</strong><br />

these Annexes, talks <strong>of</strong> the difficulties encountered in attempting to ensure that all<br />

private waste collectors operating within the County introduced a DVC mechanism.<br />

While the council operated services took the lead in the introduction <strong>of</strong> pay by weight<br />

systems, the council was limited in term <strong>of</strong> sanctions that could be imposed or<br />

enforced on operators, allowing many to continue with flat fee services.<br />

7.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

Both the EPA and DoEHLG are involved in a supervisory role in the overall<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> waste management in Ireland. Local Authorities and Private<br />

Operators are obliged to provide data on waste collection, recovery and disposal<br />

volumes to the EPA for analysis on the regional and nationwide trends and for<br />

29/09/09


eporting in the Annual National <strong>Waste</strong> Reports. These data and figures collated and<br />

reported by the EPA are used by all stakeholders in the analysis <strong>of</strong> the current status<br />

<strong>of</strong> the waste management infrastructure and in assessing ways <strong>of</strong> moving forward, as<br />

mentioned in the section below on monitoring.<br />

The EPA carried out a review in order to discern how PBU charges impact on domestic<br />

waste management activities such as waste presentation, waste recycling and illegal<br />

waste diversion. The nationwide review was conducted by collating figures on waste<br />

management behaviour and data on PBU charges for each <strong>of</strong> the 34 local authorities<br />

in Ireland.<br />

The high level <strong>of</strong> private sector involvement in waste collection means that in many<br />

cases local authorities have little control over access to information on waste<br />

collected or recycled, on systems and levels <strong>of</strong> charging and on waiver systems. This<br />

prohibits effective and accurate monitoring and assessment <strong>of</strong> the effectiveness <strong>of</strong><br />

PBU systems.<br />

7.5.1 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> studies have been completed these include:<br />

107<br />

� Davies, A., Meade, F., Taylor, D. (2005) Environmental Attitudes and<br />

Behaviour: Values, Actions and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, Final Report, Final Report<br />

Prepared for the EPA, by the Geography <strong>Department</strong>, Trinity College Dublin,<br />

Authors: ERDTI (2001-MS-SE2-M1)<br />

� Scott, S., Watson, D. (2006) Introduction <strong>of</strong> Weight-Based Charges for<br />

Domestic Solid <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal, Final Report Prepared for the EPA by the<br />

Economic and Social Research Institute, (2000-DS-6-M1)<br />

� O’Callaghan-Platt, A., Davies, A. (2007) A Nationwide <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Pay-By-Use<br />

(PBU) Domestic <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges in Ireland: Extensive Survey<br />

Findings (2005-WRM-MS-33) Interim Report, Report for the EPA, <strong>Department</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> Geography, School <strong>of</strong> Natural Sciences, Trinity College, Dublin<br />

� O’Callaghan-Platt, A., Davies, A. (2008) Nationwide <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Pay-By-Use<br />

Domestic <strong>Waste</strong> Charges in Ireland - Case Studies Report<br />

� Fehily Timoney & Company (2008) Direct and Variable Charging for Residual<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> from Householders, Report for Welsh Assembly Government, December<br />

2008, wales.gov.uk/docs/desh/consultation/090429wastechargingen.pdf<br />

This report contains a number <strong>of</strong> case studies to charging systems in Ireland in<br />

Appendix 1 <strong>of</strong> the document, with the most detail to be found in the Cork<br />

study.<br />

� ESRI (2009) An Economic Approach to Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> in<br />

Ireland, Preliminary Report for Dublin City Council, 27 July 2009.<br />

7.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

Summary findings <strong>of</strong> the 2006 report include:<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


108<br />

� Charges by weight are a strong incentive to reduce one’s weight <strong>of</strong> rubbish.<br />

The move from a flat-rate charge to the pay-by-weight charge resulted in a 45%<br />

reduction in waste collected in one sample area;<br />

� Weight reductions varied by socio–economic characteristics <strong>of</strong> the household;<br />

� Recycling was the key to waste reduction, but at the time it was only glass<br />

recycling facilities that were widely considered to be convenient;<br />

� There are economies <strong>of</strong> scale <strong>of</strong> waste generation and waste reduction with<br />

respect to numbers in the household, which are estimated in this study. The<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> waste per head decreases with increasing numbers in the<br />

household, though at a diminishing rate;<br />

� The overwhelming majority <strong>of</strong> the population have not experienced others<br />

using their bins. Experience <strong>of</strong> this tends to be confined to those in rented<br />

accommodation;<br />

� With respect to attitudes to charges, an overwhelming majority say that they<br />

would prefer the new pay-by-weight system to having to pay through other<br />

means, such as through increased income taxes; and<br />

� The majority say that the new pay-by-weight scheme is fair. However, fairness<br />

is not the verdict <strong>of</strong> over a quarter <strong>of</strong> respondents.<br />

Summary findings <strong>of</strong> the 2007/2008 reports include:<br />

� Following the introduction <strong>of</strong> the PBU systems, a decrease in the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

waste presented by households has been reported by local authorities;<br />

� Under the pay by weight system, case study areas reported reductions in the<br />

domestic waste presentation rates 142 <strong>of</strong> between 28% and 61% from the year<br />

prior to PBU up to the most recent report year <strong>of</strong> 2007;<br />

� Under the tag a bin system case study, waste presentation by householders for<br />

landfill reduced by 38% from the year prior to PBU up to the most recent report<br />

year <strong>of</strong> 2007;<br />

� It was concluded from the case studies that pay by weight is more effective for<br />

reducing household waste presentation than tag a bin;<br />

� Stage 1 <strong>of</strong> the study found that out <strong>of</strong> the survey responses from 34 local<br />

authority administrative areas, pay by weight was only in use in 15% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

areas for which responses were received, whereas pre-paid tag systems were<br />

in use in 82% <strong>of</strong> areas;<br />

� Three administrative areas examined in stage 2 <strong>of</strong> the study had moved from a<br />

flat rate to pay by weight charge. The average reduction experienced by the<br />

three areas in the presentation <strong>of</strong> waste for landfill (black bin) was 47%<br />

142 The waste-presentation rate is designated as the weight <strong>of</strong> waste presented by householders for<br />

delivery to landfill by waste collectors.<br />

29/09/09


109<br />

� In the absence <strong>of</strong> a kerbside recycling service, pay by weight will still facilitate<br />

waste reduction; one administrative area without kerbside recycling showed a<br />

reduction in the waste going to landfill <strong>of</strong> 39%;<br />

� Stage 1 <strong>of</strong> the study found that the only local authority area which does not<br />

have a kerbside recycling service has the fifth highest total waste presentation<br />

rate per person in the country. The Local Authority area with the lowest rate <strong>of</strong><br />

waste presentation, <strong>of</strong>fers kerbside recycling collections on a weekly basis<br />

throughout its functional area; and<br />

Negative Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> in relation to pollution prevention<br />

� The 2006 report finds that the number <strong>of</strong> households stating that they<br />

engaged in burning was alarming and the numbers increasing this activity<br />

under the new price regime more so;<br />

� The systems for monitoring illegal diversion <strong>of</strong> household waste are not well<br />

developed. The answer to the question <strong>of</strong> the link between the introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

Pay by Use and rates <strong>of</strong> illegal disposal <strong>of</strong> household waste is inconclusive.<br />

Stage 2 <strong>of</strong> the study, including case studies, found that just less than half <strong>of</strong><br />

the 30 interviewees experienced increases in illegal diversion <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

following the implementation <strong>of</strong> PBU.<br />

The detail <strong>of</strong> the data for the Cork County Council experience provided in the work for<br />

the Welsh Assembly Government is not sufficient to allow detailed assessment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> the operated pay by weight schemes. A reduction in kerbside collected<br />

waste occurred between 2005 and 2006, though it is not clear whether this is due to<br />

genuine waste prevention, diversion <strong>of</strong> waste to civic amenity sites, or illegal activity<br />

such as backyard burning. Total waste collected in the county fell by 3%, but it is not<br />

apparent how many households were using the collection services (whether Council<br />

or private contractor provided). The data suggests that kerbside recycling rates in the<br />

County have improved over the duration within which weight based charging has been<br />

introduced. Percentage recycling rates for contractor provided services (<strong>of</strong> which the<br />

suggestion is that some may have switched to weight based charging in recent times)<br />

increased from 22% to 26% between 2005 and 2006, and the recycling rate for local<br />

authority services increased from 15-22%. However, the degree to which this may be<br />

an effect <strong>of</strong> the weight based charge is not clear as other service changes occurred<br />

during this time (additional kerbside recycling services) and there is an admission<br />

that contamination <strong>of</strong> recycling bins by residual waste was observed.<br />

7.6.1 Benefits <strong>of</strong> Pay by Use <strong>Policy</strong> in Relation to Prevention<br />

As mentioned in the previous section the Local Authorities which implement a PBU<br />

system have found there is a decrease <strong>of</strong> (residual) waste presentation rates. This<br />

finding could indicate that PBU charges have reduced waste presentation rates in<br />

Ireland on a nationwide level. It has not been possible to determine whether this<br />

translates into a genuine impact on waste prevention in the Irish case as the data in<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


general does not allow assessment <strong>of</strong> flows <strong>of</strong> waste into alternate channels –<br />

recycling, civic amenity sites, direct delivery to landfill, or illegal disposal routes.<br />

ESRI (2009) reports: 143<br />

110<br />

29/09/09<br />

Although PBU areas saw a decline in waste presentation - 227 kg per person<br />

in 2003 to 219kg in 2005 – many collectors used volume-based charging, a<br />

system that can yield similar (ineffective) results to the flat-rate charging <strong>of</strong><br />

waste collection in the past. The average reduction found in this study is quite<br />

low by international standards. And by the end <strong>of</strong> 2006, six LAs still had waste<br />

collectors operating a flat-rate charge in parts <strong>of</strong> their functional area<br />

(O’Callaghan-Platt & Davies, 2008a).<br />

An effective PBU system sends a more accurate pricing signal to the<br />

producers <strong>of</strong> waste than a flat rate, and encourages them to reduce their<br />

waste generation, but the continued use <strong>of</strong> a flat rate or even bin-size based<br />

charging weakens this incentive to change household and business habits. In<br />

O’Callaghan-Platt and Davies’ survey, it emerged that volume-based charging<br />

is used in 62% <strong>of</strong> LAs’ functional areas, and that the price difference between<br />

a 140l and 240l bin is quite small, thus explaining in part the weak effect <strong>of</strong><br />

the PBU system in Ireland. It is notable that this form <strong>of</strong> charging is not used<br />

by any public waste collectors. This fact also illustrates the lack <strong>of</strong> control LAs<br />

have over collection practices under the current permitting system<br />

(O’Callaghan-Platt & Davies, 2008b).<br />

These observations are consistent with international experiences, where<br />

‘subscription-based’ schemes, in which householders sign up for a given service<br />

configuration for a fixed period, lead to minimal incentives, at the margin, for<br />

behavioural change. Stronger stimulus is provided by schemes where ‘frequency’ and<br />

‘weight’ are the bases for charges, with these being up to households to determine<br />

(through tagged, or other identification-based, bag and bin schemes).<br />

7.6.2 Benefits <strong>of</strong> Pay by Use <strong>Policy</strong> in Relation to Recycling<br />

The increased proportion <strong>of</strong> waste which may be recycled is also likely to have been<br />

positive. Recycling rates have certainly increased in recent years, over the time where<br />

pay-by-use has become more commonplace. However, since there have been<br />

considerable service changes during this time no quantitative assessments have<br />

been able to be made.<br />

7.6.3 Negative Impacts <strong>of</strong> Pay by Use in Relation to Recycling<br />

One negative impact <strong>of</strong> PBU appears to have been illegal dumping, and an increase in<br />

backyard burning. Scott’s work indicates very high levels <strong>of</strong> reported burning <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

143 ESRI (2009) An Economic Approach to Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> in Ireland, Preliminary<br />

Report for Dublin City Council, 27 July 2009.


in case study areas, and an increase in the quantity being burned by those who<br />

engage in the activity after the introduction <strong>of</strong> charging: 144<br />

111<br />

“The remarkable feature is the 42% <strong>of</strong> the full sample and the Clonakilty<br />

sample who say they burn household waste. In addition, the number who say<br />

that they are burning more [since the charging scheme was introduced], at<br />

33%, is practically double the number who say that they are burning less, at<br />

17%. This important finding backs up reports that that there has been an<br />

increase in burning occurring since the introduction <strong>of</strong> the pay-by-weight<br />

regime. Although the numbers <strong>of</strong> complaints about burning recorded in data<br />

from the West Cork Laboratory are small, they reveal an increase in<br />

complaints since the introduction <strong>of</strong> the new charging scheme, from an<br />

average <strong>of</strong> one per year between 1998 and 2002, to seven in 2003, 15 in<br />

2004 and nine in 2005. The numbers undoubtedly understate the true extent<br />

<strong>of</strong> burning as people are likely to be reluctant to complain. Nevertheless, they<br />

suggest that illegal means <strong>of</strong> waste disposal, such as burning, are likely to<br />

increase in response to such charges.”<br />

This suggests that the manner <strong>of</strong> implementation may be affecting the balance <strong>of</strong><br />

costs and benefits to Ireland <strong>of</strong> implementing PBU.<br />

7.7 Implementation Costs<br />

Little information is available on the costs to operators in Ireland <strong>of</strong> implementing<br />

PBU schemes. For the waste collection system as a whole, anecdotal evidence<br />

suggests that costs may have fallen as presentation rates have fallen.<br />

An associated cost implication <strong>of</strong> delivering the PBU system, is that in order to<br />

incentivise separating the waste into segregated waste streams at the household<br />

level, the corresponding infrastructure in terms <strong>of</strong> recycling and recovery facilities<br />

have to be available to the waste collector following collection <strong>of</strong> the waste, whether<br />

the facility is managed by the same operator, or whether the facility is that <strong>of</strong> another<br />

operator. Many Local Authorities pointed to a lack <strong>of</strong> recycling and recovery<br />

infrastructure as the reason behind a delay in the provision and roll out <strong>of</strong> PBU and<br />

separated waste collection services.<br />

7.8 Response from Public and Industry<br />

One study assessed public responses to PBU in two communities. The key results are<br />

shown in Table 7-1. The majority feel that charging is fair. The authors speculate as to<br />

reasons for views that charging is unfair: 145<br />

144 Sue Scott and Dorothy Watson (2006) Introduction <strong>of</strong> Weight-Based Charges for Domestic Solid<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Disposal, Final Report Prepared for the EPA by the Economic and Social Research Institute,<br />

(2000-DS-6-M1).<br />

145 Sue Scott and Dorothy Watson (2006) Introduction <strong>of</strong> Weight-Based Charges for Domestic Solid<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Disposal, Final Report Prepared for the EPA by the Economic and Social Research Institute,<br />

(2000-DS-6-M1).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


112<br />

29/09/09<br />

“However, over one-quarter disagree and this may reflect the fact that they<br />

are unfamiliar with the waiver system or that they do not think that the<br />

waivers adequately meet the needs <strong>of</strong> certain households. They may also feel<br />

that some people generate waste through no fault <strong>of</strong> their own and yet have to<br />

pay. There is also the issue that tax relief on the waste charge is granted to<br />

compliant customers, but those that are not earning sufficient money to be in<br />

the tax net cannot avail <strong>of</strong> the relief.”<br />

The most negative attitude was reflected by the 47% <strong>of</strong> respondents who felt that it<br />

had increased the mess and bother <strong>of</strong> waste disposal. This might reflect a lack <strong>of</strong> a<br />

wide scope <strong>of</strong> recycling service, with only glass recycling considered to be convenient<br />

in these areas.<br />

Table 7-1: Perceptions <strong>of</strong> the New Pay-by-weight Scheme<br />

Possible views about the new pay-byweight<br />

scheme<br />

Agree<br />

Neither agree nor<br />

disagree<br />

Disagree<br />

New pay-by-weight scheme is fair 64% 8% 28%<br />

New scheme encourages households to<br />

reduce waste<br />

93% 4% 3%<br />

Makes people more aware <strong>of</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

waste disposal<br />

90% 4% 5%<br />

Better than the old flat annual charge 56% 13% 31%<br />

Better than paying through an increase<br />

in income tax<br />

78% 15% 8%<br />

Scheme has increased mess and bother<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste disposal<br />

47% 11% 42%<br />

Feel I have enough information on<br />

recycling and other methods<br />

71% 3% 26%<br />

Source: Sue Scott and Dorothy Watson (2006) Introduction <strong>of</strong> Weight-Based Charges for Domestic<br />

Solid <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal, Final Report Prepared for the EPA by the Economic and Social Research<br />

Institute, (2000-DS-6-M1).<br />

7.9 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

PBU has resulted in new waste collection technologies. Under the pay by weight<br />

scheme each residual waste collection vehicle is installed with weighing equipment<br />

designed to weigh wheeled bins as they are lifted into the truck. Every bin is fitted<br />

with a microchip in the underside <strong>of</strong> the lip <strong>of</strong> the bin. Each chip has the individual<br />

householder’s details scanned onto it. When a bin is emptied a microchip reader on<br />

the back <strong>of</strong> the truck sends the information to the on board computer. The<br />

information gathered is then downloaded to an invoicing system and this is how<br />

householders can then be billed in accordance with the weight <strong>of</strong> waste they produce<br />

for disposal.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> collection vehicles with separated compartments within the trucks to allow for<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> both residual black bin waste and dry recyclables have been developed.<br />

This allows the collection <strong>of</strong> both types <strong>of</strong> materials in the same route shift coverage<br />

on the same day using the same staffing (administrative) resource to achieve the<br />

objective. This development has occurred in response to the alternative<br />

administrative cost option <strong>of</strong> collecting the material in separate trucks, on separate


shifts/by separate staff, which in some cases posed administrative and cost<br />

restrictions to operators.<br />

There are an increasing number <strong>of</strong> recycling and recovery treatment facilities being<br />

developed in Ireland to deal with the growing amount <strong>of</strong> segregated recyclable<br />

material. The degree to which charging can be considered responsible for this is<br />

difficult to estimate.<br />

At the household level, it seems clear that one undesirable innovation is the tendency<br />

to resort to (increased) burning <strong>of</strong> waste. Some households may also choose not to<br />

avail themselves <strong>of</strong> a service, though whether and how this has changed as a<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> PBU is not clear. Others may simply choose to deliver waste direct to<br />

available facilities. On the more positive side, there may be increased sorting <strong>of</strong><br />

wastes, and an improvement in waste prevention behaviours. However, an<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> the extent <strong>of</strong> these effects across Ireland is not available.<br />

7.10 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

A study was completed in 2004 by the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Geography in Trinity College, on<br />

“Environmental attitudes and behaviour: values, actions and waste management”. 146<br />

This survey revealed that respondents understood that it was necessary to pay for<br />

waste management. However there was concern that the level <strong>of</strong> waste charges did<br />

not reflect the standard <strong>of</strong> service provided. Providing a pay-by-weight system was a<br />

popular suggestion amongst respondents who felt people would then attain a double<br />

benefit for reducing waste– moral (in terms <strong>of</strong> benefiting future generations and the<br />

environment) and financial (in terms <strong>of</strong> saving money).<br />

As mentioned above, a study following the introduction <strong>of</strong> PBU suggested that around<br />

three-quarters <strong>of</strong> respondents thought PBU was fair.<br />

As mentioned previously, the overwhelming majority <strong>of</strong> the population have not<br />

experienced others using their bins. Experience <strong>of</strong> this tends to be confined to those<br />

in rented accommodation. Therefore, evasion <strong>of</strong> payment in terms <strong>of</strong> the pollution<br />

pays principle does not seem to occur through use <strong>of</strong> neighbours bins.<br />

Some Local Authorities point to what they identify as a broader expense base<br />

concerning waste management (over which costs need to be recovered) than that<br />

which is imposed on private operators. There is a divergence among Local Authorities<br />

as to what constitutes their public service obligations in the provision <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management services. Some Local Authorities point out that there is no specific<br />

obligation placed upon them under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Acts to provide a<br />

household waste collection service, and in some cases have withdrawn totally from<br />

household waste collection; other Local Authorities interpret their public service<br />

obligations as requiring the provision <strong>of</strong> a networked waste management service,<br />

where the efficacy and efficiency in the provision <strong>of</strong> household waste collection is<br />

influenced by the costs <strong>of</strong> provision <strong>of</strong> other service elements e.g. infrastructure in<br />

146 EPA /TCD Anna Davies, Frances Fahy Honora Meade & David Taylor (2005) Environmental<br />

Attitudes and Behaviour: Values, Actions and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>,<br />

113<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


terms <strong>of</strong> waste processing and disposal facilities and programmes for education and<br />

prevention.<br />

As a result <strong>of</strong> this, those Local Authorities who have remained in the household waste<br />

collection system, have identified difficulties in recovering (what they feel are) the<br />

total costs incurred in the implementation <strong>of</strong> the PBU / separated household waste<br />

collection service at a price competitive with collection fees charged by other<br />

operators in the market.<br />

7.11 Complementary Policies<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> policies exist which compliment changes in the presentation <strong>of</strong> waste at<br />

household level. These policies are complementary because they aim to achieve<br />

some <strong>of</strong> the same objectives, including the minimisation <strong>of</strong> waste materials and<br />

household waste generated, and an increase in the amounts being recycled with the<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> materials and energy recovery. These are:<br />

114<br />

� The Landfill Levy (see Annex 11.0);<br />

� The Circular WPPR 17/08 (see Annex 33.0); and<br />

� The Packaging Regulations.<br />

7.12 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The intention <strong>of</strong> PBU is to give incentives to households to use the waste<br />

management service in a more efficient manner. The degree to which PBU has<br />

achieved this objective depends upon the specifics <strong>of</strong> the charging mechanism used.<br />

Other things being equal, however, the aim is to ensure that, at the margin,<br />

households consider the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste they generate and how it is managed.<br />

Although recycling rates have increased, depending upon charging structures used,<br />

the system has the disadvantage <strong>of</strong> allowing households to believe that recycling is<br />

‘free’. 147 Some pricing structures – possibly most to date – have not highlighted the<br />

fact that collection and processing <strong>of</strong> all waste, whether black bin, green bin or brown<br />

bin, has associated expenses. The issue ought to be about setting the right price<br />

differentials. Furthermore, <strong>of</strong>fering a ‘free’ recycling service and a relatively high<br />

marginal charge on refuse may have the effect <strong>of</strong> increasing the level <strong>of</strong><br />

contamination <strong>of</strong> the recycling containers if, at the margin, the incentive is high, and<br />

the potential for quality checks is low (as it undoubtedly is with bin-based recycling<br />

schemes).<br />

In addition some Local Authorities have been dissatisfied with the lack <strong>of</strong><br />

transparency in the charging systems used by private waste collectors within their<br />

functional area. The local authority state that itemised bills are not issued to<br />

householders by collectors (at least in the case <strong>of</strong> fixed fee, tag based or potentially<br />

volume based charging) prompting the concern that the reduced waste to landfill is<br />

147 A. O Callaghan-Platt and A. Davies (2007) A Nationwide <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Pay-By-Use Domestic <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Charges in Ireland, Interim Report to the EPA.<br />

29/09/09


not reflected in reduced costs to consumers. This may reduce householders’ ability to<br />

see the real benefit <strong>of</strong> source reduction. 148<br />

7.13 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Where pay-by-use is concerned, households’ response to charging for services is to<br />

seek to reduce exposure to the charge. This can take forms which are both legal and<br />

illegal in nature. Some, such as burning, are not illegal per se, but they may cause<br />

nuisance. Emissions from domestic premises are covered under the Air Pollution Act<br />

1987. This Act gives local authorities the lead role in control <strong>of</strong> air pollutants from<br />

premises. Section 24(2) <strong>of</strong> the Act imposes a general obligation on the occupier ‘not<br />

to cause or permit an emission in such a quantity or in such a manner as to be a<br />

nuisance.’ The Act, though somewhat unspecific, is <strong>of</strong> significance to domestic<br />

burning, though it is not exactly clear what constitutes a nuisance. The responses to<br />

the survey could under-represent the amount <strong>of</strong> burning if householders are aware <strong>of</strong><br />

the Act and it is possible that there is uncertainty in the public mind about the legality<br />

<strong>of</strong> burning and about differentiation by material.<br />

In 2005 the EPA published a Report on “The Nature and Extent <strong>of</strong> Unauthorised<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Activity in Ireland”. This report sets out the findings <strong>of</strong> a nationwide<br />

investigation by the EPA’s Office <strong>of</strong> Environmental Enforcement (OEE) on the nature<br />

and extent <strong>of</strong> unauthorised waste management activities in Ireland from the period<br />

1996 onward. This report stated:<br />

115<br />

“every year, in the region <strong>of</strong> 287,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> household waste is not<br />

presented for collection with this waste being disposed <strong>of</strong> by the householders<br />

themselves. Many local authorities have reported recent increases in<br />

backyard burning and fly-tipping <strong>of</strong> household waste which, anecdotally, is<br />

being linked to the increases in household waste charges” 149 .<br />

There appears, therefore, to be a problem in terms <strong>of</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> enforcement <strong>of</strong> matters<br />

related to illegal tipping and burning in the Irish context. The extent to which this is<br />

something which would occur in the absence <strong>of</strong> charging is unclear, though it seems<br />

reasonable to believe that these are matters which are problematic even in the<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> PBU, but which PBU exacerbates.<br />

One can also argue that some collectors have evaded, or are still evading, the<br />

requirement to implement PBU. By not enforcing the requirement to make PBU<br />

mandatory, local authorities allow collectors to continue to operate on a flat fee basis.<br />

Concerns have been raised by local authorities that they had little ability to enforce<br />

PBU systems if private collectors did not use them. In principle, permits for private<br />

waste-collection companies could contain more requirements with regards to PBU<br />

charges, with the threat <strong>of</strong> revocation <strong>of</strong> the permit if a PBU system is not<br />

implemented by the collector.<br />

148 A. O Callaghan-Platt and A. Davies (2007) A Nationwide <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Pay-By-Use Domestic <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Charges in Ireland, Interim Report to the EPA.<br />

149 EPA (2005) The Nature and Extent <strong>of</strong> Unauthorised <strong>Waste</strong> Activity in Ireland, EPA, 2005.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


7.14 Lessons Learned<br />

7.14.1 General Lessons<br />

Most policy statements regarding waste have assumed that there will be benefits to<br />

be derived from implementation <strong>of</strong> PBU. However, the benefits are likely to be<br />

assured only where conditions are such as to maximise the benefits and minimise the<br />

potential for perverse consequences.<br />

There are a growing number <strong>of</strong> studies evaluating PBU in Ireland. These seem to have<br />

been conducted mainly from an academic perspective, with less attention given to<br />

key operational issues than may be warranted. Evidently, illegal dumping and burning<br />

are problematic, but even those studies which highlight this as an issue make no<br />

recommendations as to how this should be addressed. As such, it is not clear that<br />

lessons are necessarily being learned in respect <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> PBU in Ireland.<br />

Key issues, in our view, relate to the current level <strong>of</strong> service coverage, to the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

charging structures, and to the simple fact that households are not required to avail<br />

themselves <strong>of</strong> the collection service.<br />

One study suggests that pay-by-weight is generally believed to be more effective at<br />

reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> household waste sent to landfill compared to tag-based<br />

systems. However the nationwide survey (Stage 1) found that pay-by-weight was only<br />

in use in 15% <strong>of</strong> local authorities, whereas tag-based is in use in 82% <strong>of</strong> local<br />

authorities in the country. The study suggests that as pay-by-weight is more effective,<br />

there maybe a requirement to incentivise this form <strong>of</strong> PBU. However, there are likely<br />

to be more fundamental issues which need to be considered regarding<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> PBU in Ireland, notably the degree to which implementation can be<br />

expected to lead to the most advantageous outcomes where the market for collection<br />

is configured as a free one.<br />

Of some interest is the fact that although several studies purport to address the<br />

economics <strong>of</strong> waste collection, the focus has been on behavioural responses (what<br />

charge gives what outcome in terms <strong>of</strong> waste quantities), and still, there is a paucity<br />

<strong>of</strong> studies seeking to understand the implications <strong>of</strong> different approaches to PBU for<br />

the costs <strong>of</strong> service provision (as opposed to quantities <strong>of</strong> waste). The costs <strong>of</strong><br />

collection systems are affected by the frequency <strong>of</strong> pick-ups, and whilst weight-based<br />

charges are likely to generate marginal reductions in the weight <strong>of</strong> waste set out, they<br />

do not necessarily incentivise reduced set-out frequencies (and hence, collection<br />

costs). Indeed, they can, in the absence <strong>of</strong> shifts in frequency, lead to inefficient<br />

logistics in terms <strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> collection <strong>of</strong> refuse. More work is warranted on<br />

understanding collection costs (that is to say, costs, not charges – the two are not<br />

necessarily the same in the Irish market), and the effect <strong>of</strong> the charging approaches<br />

on these in Ireland.<br />

Generally, in Ireland, implementation <strong>of</strong> pay by use systems may be considered<br />

somewhat unique. In many regions, it remains the case that large proportions <strong>of</strong><br />

households are not ‘connected’ to any household waste collection system. In the<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> thorough recycling and composting collection systems, and with the<br />

choice <strong>of</strong> residual waste service provider left to the individual household pay by use is<br />

likely, in some regions, to have reduced the number who avail themselves <strong>of</strong> any<br />

collection service. The risk here is that illegal behaviour becomes widespread, and the<br />

116<br />

29/09/09


extent to which this compromises any attempts to model household behavioural<br />

responses in this regard is not entirely clear (not least since the quantities within and<br />

without the collection system may change if households decide to opt-in or opt-out as<br />

a consequence <strong>of</strong> the charging system itself). This issue <strong>of</strong> the effect <strong>of</strong> charges on<br />

actual service take-up is also not widely explored in the existing literature. Its<br />

relevance in Ireland stems from the absence <strong>of</strong> a requirement on households to use<br />

the waste collection service.<br />

117<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


8.0 Pay-by-use - <strong>International</strong><br />

8.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Charging for waste (commonly referred to under a variety <strong>of</strong> titles including ‘User<br />

Pays’, ‘Differential and Variable Rate charging’ (DVR), ‘Pay-As-You-Throw’ (PAYT), or<br />

‘Pay-by-weight’ charging), is an approach whereby a business or individual is subject<br />

to a fee which is linked to some quantitative measure <strong>of</strong> waste set out for collection.<br />

National government has the authority to prescribe in law the rights and<br />

responsibilities <strong>of</strong> the local authorities or municipalities responsible for organising<br />

and administering waste management. Typically, this will either allow (for example<br />

Germany, Italy, Ireland) or prohibit (for example England) local authorities from<br />

charging households for waste services. 150 It is <strong>of</strong>ten up to the discretion <strong>of</strong> individual<br />

authorities how charging systems are operated on the local level. Some countries,<br />

such as South Korea, and some regions within countries, have made pay-by-use<br />

mandatory.<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> different motivations for introducing charging schemes. These<br />

include cost recovery, creating an economic incentive to reduce waste, and/or<br />

creating an economic incentive to recycle or recover waste, as well as improving data<br />

collection and the efficiency <strong>of</strong> collection logistics. A typical pay-by-use approach is<br />

shown in the following ideological pricing structure, with the total fees paid covering<br />

the full costs <strong>of</strong> collection, recovery, treatment and disposal, as well any monetised<br />

environmental damage costs (where environmental taxation can be used to <strong>of</strong>fset<br />

damages caused):<br />

118<br />

� Flat rate service provision fee;<br />

� Recycling – zero or low variable fee;<br />

� Organic waste – zero or low / medium variable fee;<br />

� Residual waste – higher variable fee.<br />

Economic theory suggests that there are likely to be two responses where services<br />

are charged for:<br />

� Reduction in demand for the service (output effect); and<br />

� Resort to alternatives (switching effect).<br />

As such, the strongest impact on waste prevention may be expected where a charge<br />

is placed on all collection streams, including recyclable materials. The charge<br />

differentials ought to be significant enough to encourage separation, the recycling fee<br />

low enough to maintain use <strong>of</strong> the service but still sufficient to promote prevention,<br />

150 Section 45 <strong>of</strong> the Environmental Protection Act 1990 states “No No charge shall be made for for the the<br />

collection collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> household household waste waste except in [specific] cases…” and furthermore “It shall be the duty <strong>of</strong> each<br />

waste collection authority… to make such arrangements for the emptying, without charge charge, charge<br />

<strong>of</strong> privies<br />

serving one or more private dwellings…”<br />

29/09/09


and residual waste fee not so great as to encourage illegal disposal. The flat rate fee<br />

element is important to help balance these objectives. It can also be used to ensure<br />

that the costs <strong>of</strong> service provision are covered, even where waste prevention and<br />

recycling behaviour improves significantly (in which case, in the absence <strong>of</strong> a flat fee<br />

raises the issue <strong>of</strong> revenue instability).<br />

The range <strong>of</strong> approaches to pay-by-use includes systems where households are<br />

charged based on:<br />

1) The weight <strong>of</strong> material set out;<br />

2) The volume <strong>of</strong> material generated;<br />

3) The frequency <strong>of</strong> collection; or<br />

4) A combination <strong>of</strong> these factors.<br />

The following sections describe the approach used in particular countries and, based<br />

on a desktop evaluation <strong>of</strong> available literature, assess the success <strong>of</strong> particular<br />

approaches and the impact on waste prevention.<br />

8.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

The following sub-sections give the background to selected countries which operate<br />

waste charging systems. Assessment <strong>of</strong> the systems, and other evidence where<br />

available, is given under the standard headings used through this report in the<br />

sections that follow. Section 8.5 <strong>of</strong> this report in particular attempts to assess the<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> charging on waste prevention and recycling. This is done by drawing<br />

evidence from individual case studies to assess particular charging mechanisms,<br />

rather than by assessing charging on a country by country basis (which would disguise<br />

the impacts <strong>of</strong> particular locally implemented approaches).<br />

We have focussed our attention on a range <strong>of</strong> examples from counties where lessons<br />

can be learnt from the charging systems employed.<br />

In individual countries, different parts <strong>of</strong> the infrastructure may operate somewhat<br />

differently. In particular, the scope <strong>of</strong> kerbside collections in countries such as<br />

Denmark tends to be very narrow (sometimes, just paper and card and glass are<br />

collected at kerbside). In the Netherlands, the scope tends to include biowaste (and<br />

prior to the introduction <strong>of</strong> charging systems, garden waste has typically been<br />

collected free <strong>of</strong> charge), though it does not always include all packaging fractions. In<br />

other countries, notably Belgium, Austria and Germany, the scope <strong>of</strong> kerbside<br />

systems is much more comprehensive. Bring sites tend to be more important in<br />

countries such as Denmark, the Netherlands, Sweden and Norway. Of course, there is<br />

local variation in the scope <strong>of</strong> kerbside collection schemes in most countries, but this<br />

is less true in countries / regions where:<br />

119<br />

� Ordinances are in place for the collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste (Austrian, Germany,<br />

Catalonia (Spain), Flanders (Belgium), and ‘voluntarily’ in the Netherlands);<br />

� Producer responsibility (see Annexes 19.0 to 26.0) measures require<br />

commodity related organisations to fund, more or less completely, the<br />

kerbside collection <strong>of</strong> various materials, notably packaging materials<br />

(examples <strong>of</strong> ‘full financial responsibility’ being Germany, Austria, Belgium);<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


120<br />

� There are stipulations as to which materials should be collected and with<br />

which frequency (most notably, Flanders in Belgium).<br />

In these cases, local variation is somewhat reduced. Some examples <strong>of</strong> how the<br />

approach is implemented in different countries is given below.<br />

8.2.1 Denmark<br />

In Denmark, municipalities (local councils) are responsible for managing all waste,<br />

including municipal waste generated in their territories. Responsibilities include<br />

collection, transport, sorting, storage, composting, recycling, incineration, treatment<br />

and disposal <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

Pursuant to the Environmental Protection Act, municipalities can determine a fee that<br />

covers the costs <strong>of</strong> planning, establishing, operating and administrating waste<br />

collection schemes, and <strong>of</strong> establishing and operating waste processing and disposal<br />

facilities, the collection and registration <strong>of</strong> information, and advance payment <strong>of</strong><br />

planned investments in the field <strong>of</strong> waste management. As such, in almost all<br />

municipalities, the costs <strong>of</strong> waste management are fully covered by fees.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> fees are typically collected on the same bill as the real estate tax. Earlier in this<br />

decade, just 6 <strong>of</strong> the 275 municipalities were presenting a separate bill. 151<br />

Of the municipalities that have a differentiated waste fee, most have a weight-based<br />

payment system, a few have volume-based payment system. Approximately 10% <strong>of</strong><br />

Danish municipalities have weight-based schemes for household and small<br />

company/institution waste. The first scheme was introduced in 1991 in Tinglev<br />

municipality.<br />

All the municipalities that have introduced a weight-based collection scheme are<br />

small or medium-sized rural municipalities with few multi-storey buildings. Other<br />

municipalities charge an additional fixed fee if the amount <strong>of</strong> waste set out by a<br />

household exceeds the amount on which the fee is calculated (e.g. two bags instead<br />

<strong>of</strong> one).<br />

8.2.2 Italy<br />

The National <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act (Decree 22/97, also called the Ronchi Decree)<br />

in Italy delegates the responsibility for organising the collection, transport and<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> municipal and comparable waste to municipalities (Article 21). Municipal<br />

tasks mandated by Decree 22/97 include:<br />

� Organization <strong>of</strong> collection <strong>of</strong> MSW and its transportation to treatment and<br />

disposal facilities. This can be done also in association with other<br />

municipalities;<br />

151 Eunomia (2003) To Charge or Not to Charge? Final report to IWM (EB). Referred to hereafter as the<br />

‘IWM charging review’.<br />

29/09/09


121<br />

� Choosing collection schemes and tools most suited to achieve the targets<br />

mandated by the Decree (e.g. doorstep collection, road containers, civic<br />

amenity sites, etc.)<br />

� The assessment <strong>of</strong> contributions for the MSW tax; this includes specific<br />

parameters to be defined for each category (type <strong>of</strong> dwelling, commercial<br />

activity, etc) and tax savings for households with low incomes or belonging to<br />

particular categories (e.g. with a single person, or doing home composting,<br />

etc.).<br />

The municipality has to consider any guidance or guidelines issued by Institutions at<br />

higher levels (districts, provinces, etc.), though adherence to such guidelines is not<br />

compulsory; in particular, the strategies defined by the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan<br />

issued by the region and/or the province have to be considered.<br />

Before 1999, all businesses and citizens in Italy paid a waste management levy<br />

(typically based on the size and type <strong>of</strong> property) related to the overall cost <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management but unrelated to the individual quantities <strong>of</strong> waste produced. This<br />

meant cross-subsidisation <strong>of</strong> high waste producing households by low waste<br />

producers, as well as subsidisation <strong>of</strong> household produced waste by businesses.<br />

Along with the Ronchi Decree, the Decree <strong>of</strong> the President <strong>of</strong> the Republic 158/1999<br />

provides the basis for a new system <strong>of</strong> waste management charging based upon ‘payby-use’<br />

systems. It was the Ronchi Decree which first gave voice to the principle <strong>of</strong><br />

pay-by-use, but although the Decree contains this as a general principle, it is the later<br />

Decree which provides for implementation details. It was intended that as <strong>of</strong> January<br />

2008, all municipalities would be operating a variable charge system constituting two<br />

parts:<br />

� A fixed portion determined by the basic components <strong>of</strong> the service, particularly<br />

investment and depreciation;<br />

� A variable portion linked to the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste produced, service provided,<br />

and management costs, in order to ensure full coverage <strong>of</strong> investment and<br />

operational costs.<br />

Further simplified details on fee structuring from the legislation are given in Table 8-1.<br />

Table 8-1: Parameters for Application <strong>of</strong> the Fee in Italy<br />

Type Type <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> user user<br />

Terms Terms for for determining determining the the fee fee<br />

Reduction<br />

Reduction<br />

Fixed Fixed portion portion<br />

Variable Variable portion portion<br />

Variable Variable portion<br />

portion<br />

Household<br />

Household<br />

Non-<br />

Non<br />

household<br />

household<br />

Area and factor relative<br />

to the size <strong>of</strong> the<br />

household<br />

Area and waste<br />

production factor per<br />

activity<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Quantity <strong>of</strong> waste produced and<br />

factor relative to the size <strong>of</strong> the<br />

household<br />

Quantity <strong>of</strong> waste produced and<br />

production factor per activity<br />

Participation in<br />

sorting schemes<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> intended for<br />

recovery<br />

Source: The IWM charging review: Eunomia (2003) To Charge or Not to Charge? Final report to IWM(EB)<br />

It may also be noted that collection <strong>of</strong> dry recyclables is partially subsidised by the<br />

producer responsibility organisation, the National Association <strong>of</strong> Packaging Producers<br />

(CONAI). Each municipality receives financial support proportional to the quantity and


quality for materials collected, though this typically only partially covers the collection<br />

costs for these materials. Producer responsibility for packaging and other materials is<br />

studied separately in Annexes 19.0 to 26.0.<br />

8.2.3 United States<br />

In the United States, the role <strong>of</strong> state government is to develop plans and standards,<br />

while local government implements solid waste policy. Thus, individual states and<br />

municipalities typically develop municipal solid waste (MSW) management plans<br />

within which direct charging systems can be proposed and consulted upon. As such,<br />

charging systems in the U.S. have evolved over time. In the past, markets for waste<br />

were highly decentralised (with householders taking waste to dumps). Once it was<br />

decided to run more formalized collection operations, two main routes were followed:<br />

a) an equivalent to a local authority run collection service, accompanied by local<br />

authority billing, and b) a contract / franchise approach, the key difference being that<br />

in the latter the contractor / franchisee (not the municipality) was responsible for<br />

billing households. 152<br />

Municipalities have been able to pass ordinances asking households to 'hire their<br />

own company', and although examples <strong>of</strong> this competitive model (similar to the<br />

approaches in Ireland) still exist, a single collector is now the norm.<br />

The number <strong>of</strong> municipalities using PAYT schemes in the US stands at more than<br />

6,000, covering a population <strong>of</strong> 50 million. Pay-per-bin and pay-per-bag schemes are<br />

the most commonly used, though weight based systems have seen increasing<br />

prevalence (27 communities in the state <strong>of</strong> Maine alone by 2006). 153 154<br />

8.2.4 Korea<br />

Korea became the first country to introduce a mandatory DVR scheme country wide<br />

when, in 1995, the volume-based waste fee (VBWF) was introduced. The VBWF is<br />

essentially a pay-per-sack scheme under which households are required to place<br />

residual waste in pre-paid sacks whilst recyclables are collected free <strong>of</strong> charge.<br />

Charges are also levied on the collection <strong>of</strong> bulky wastes.<br />

In recent years, the country has introduced free food waste collections for<br />

households, having commenced collections for larger producers <strong>of</strong> food waste (such<br />

as restaurants) in 1997. In 2005, the landfilling <strong>of</strong> kitchen waste from households<br />

was banned.<br />

152 Thomas Kinnaman and Don Fullerton (1999) The Economics <strong>of</strong> Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, NBER<br />

Working Paper 7326, Massachussets, August 1999.<br />

153 Lisa Skumatz (2002) Variable Rate or ‘Pay-as-you-throw’ <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Answers to<br />

Frequently Asked Questions, Los Angeles: Reason Foundation, July 2002.<br />

154 Jan Canterbury, Sue Eisenfeld (2006) The Rise and . . . Rise <strong>of</strong> Pay-As-You-Throw, MSW<br />

<strong>Management</strong>, Elements, www.mswmanagement.com/elements-2006/waste-managementchallenges.aspx.<br />

122<br />

29/09/09


8.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The usual approach is for national government to write into law the framework within<br />

which local government and waste collectors can operate. In most situations, the<br />

local authority, or a contractor to the local authority, provides the collection service to<br />

householders.<br />

The service is funded typically through a combination <strong>of</strong>:<br />

123<br />

• Central government taxation;<br />

• Taxes raised at the local level; and<br />

• The revenue from the variable charge element.<br />

As such, the actors involved usually include local, and sometimes, central<br />

government, as well as local government and the service operator, where this is not<br />

the municipality itself.<br />

Concerns generally arise with regard to the issue <strong>of</strong> fly-tipping. As a result, local<br />

authorities and other competent authorities also have some involvement in the<br />

matter. This may bring environmental protection agencies into play (as an enforcer).<br />

8.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The list <strong>of</strong> studies that have been undertaken in respect <strong>of</strong> waste charging is<br />

extensive. However, much <strong>of</strong> the literature reports only on the high level outcomes in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> recycling and waste reduction. Rarely is there much by way <strong>of</strong> detailed<br />

discussion as to the outcomes <strong>of</strong> the scheme, and how these might be explained<br />

through reference to the specifics <strong>of</strong> the charging scheme, and the background<br />

collection system against which charges are introduced. Indeed, this has been one <strong>of</strong><br />

the main drivers behind our own attempts to carry out more detailed case studies in<br />

previous work. 155 156 157<br />

Other studies <strong>of</strong> interest are referred to through the body <strong>of</strong> this review.<br />

A recent study includes a summarised evidence base regarding the pros and cons <strong>of</strong><br />

charging systems with a reference list extending to over 50 case study reviews. The<br />

literature review covered Australia, Austria, Belgium (Flanders and Wallonia), Canada,<br />

Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, South Korea, Spain,<br />

155 Eunomia (2003) To Charge or Not to Charge? Final report to IWM (EB).<br />

156 Eunomia (2005) Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Local Authority Experience <strong>of</strong> Operating Household <strong>Waste</strong> Incentive<br />

Schemes, Defra.<br />

157 D. Hogg (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges. Referred to within the text <strong>of</strong> this<br />

report as ‘the OECD charging review’. ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Switzerland, the US, and New Zealand. 158 We draw heavily from this source for the<br />

details given here and refer to it subsequently as ‘the Defra charging report’.<br />

8.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

Charging for waste has an effect both on waste prevention and on quantities <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

separated for recycling. Where possible, the two are considered separately in the<br />

following subsections. In the first instance, it is important to establish that when we<br />

talk about the recycling and prevention, that these are proxies for environmental<br />

effectiveness.<br />

8.5.1 Evidence <strong>of</strong> Environmental Effectiveness<br />

8.5.1.1 Benefits Related to <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

Charging for waste can be one <strong>of</strong> the most direct and influential approaches to<br />

stimulating waste prevention. This was a key conclusion <strong>of</strong> a review <strong>of</strong> existing<br />

policies which have potential to encourage prevention <strong>of</strong> household waste. 159<br />

Because it is a mechanism that acts directly at the point where a product becomes a<br />

waste, it can deliver the incentive to an individual or organisation to change waste<br />

production behaviour. The charges on waste can act to discourage consumption (and<br />

related waste production) and encourage individuals to take management<br />

responsibility for avoidable wastes (for example home composting).<br />

The environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> waste prevention have been long recognised, and are<br />

reflected as such at the top <strong>of</strong> the familiar waste hierarchy. However, where municipal<br />

waste is concerned, the environmental benefits are more <strong>of</strong>ten assumed than<br />

identified in detail. Indeed, the matter is not entirely straightforward. For example, the<br />

magnitude <strong>of</strong> the benefits <strong>of</strong> preventing waste in the form <strong>of</strong> paper depend upon<br />

whether or not that paper was made from virgin materials or from recycled ones. 160<br />

Consequently, we might assume that the benefits from waste prevention change as<br />

the recycled content <strong>of</strong> the material / product which is the subject <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

prevention activity increases or declines.<br />

Within this section (and indeed throughout this report) we use the proxy that:<br />

124<br />

29/09/09<br />

“<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention = Environmental Benefit”.<br />

This assumption is likely to be a reasonable one whether the effect is on the<br />

hazardousness <strong>of</strong> waste (which is clearly an environmental benefit) or on the quantity<br />

158 D. Hogg, D. Wilson, A. Gibbs, M. Astley and J. Papineschi (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong> Household<br />

Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra. Referred to within the text <strong>of</strong> this report as ‘the<br />

Defra charging report’.<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/environment/waste/strategy/incentives/pdf/wasteincentives-research-0507.pdf<br />

159 Eunomia et al (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report<br />

for Defra, April 2007.<br />

160 See, for example, USEPA (2002) Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Greenhouse Gases: A Life-Cycle<br />

Assessment <strong>of</strong> Emissions and Sinks, EPA530-R-02-006, May 2002.


<strong>of</strong> material generated as waste (since avoiding the production <strong>of</strong> waste entails a<br />

reduction in primary or secondary material demand and associated reductions in<br />

energy use, hidden material flows, pollution and other general adverse impacts on the<br />

environment and human health).<br />

There are likely to be possible exceptions to this rule. For example, if home<br />

composting <strong>of</strong> organics effectively prevents the anaerobic digestion <strong>of</strong> the same<br />

material, then it is possible that there may be a negative environmental benefit.<br />

Home composting does eliminate the environmental impacts associated with<br />

vehicular transport, but these tend to be a relatively minor contributor to the overall<br />

environmental impacts associated with waste (though this assumes that the systems<br />

for collecting waste are efficient ones). In our analysis, however, even though the<br />

environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> home composting may be inferior to well performing<br />

anaerobic digestion systems, the cost savings implied may justify the loss in<br />

environmental benefit. 161<br />

8.5.1.2 Evidence <strong>of</strong> Environmental Benefits Related to Recycling<br />

Compared to waste prevention, the environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling are typically<br />

easier to quantify and, under the majority <strong>of</strong> circumstances, tend to be positive.<br />

Recycling post consumer waste into new products gives environmental benefits<br />

associated with the avoided extraction <strong>of</strong> primary materials, and the balance <strong>of</strong><br />

energy consumption between manufacture from primary and secondary materials.<br />

Typically, product manufacture from recycled material uses significantly less energy,<br />

and produces less emissions compared with manufacture from primary resources. A<br />

policy guidance note for UK government indicates that recycling paper can entail 28-<br />

70% less energy use, produces 95% fewer emissions, requires less water, and far<br />

fewer raw materials. Similarly, producing aluminium from recycled materials uses only<br />

5% <strong>of</strong> the energy used in primary production and generates only 5% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

greenhouse gas emissions associated with manufacture from raw materials. Again,<br />

making carrier bags from recycled plastic consumes two thirds less energy, releases<br />

lower levels <strong>of</strong> pollutants and uses nearly 90% less water than manufacture from<br />

primary polymer. 162<br />

As such, within this report we also use the proxy that:<br />

125<br />

“Recycling = Environmental Benefit”.<br />

We can, however, look to the literature to confirm this. The OECD charging review<br />

assesses the private costs <strong>of</strong> waste management considered alongside monetised<br />

environmental costs and benefits associated with avoided energy usage in the<br />

manufacture <strong>of</strong> products and the reduction in environmental damage resulting from<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> residual waste. Of particular interest is the study into the Belgian<br />

experience <strong>of</strong> Ghent and Destelbergen. Figure 8-1 (taken from the OECD review)<br />

161 See Eunomia (2007) Managing Biowastes from Households in the UK: Applying Life-cycle Thinking<br />

in the Framework <strong>of</strong> Cost-benefit Analysis, Banbury, Oxon: WRAP.<br />

162 The Parliamentary Office <strong>of</strong> Science and Technology (2005) Recycling Household <strong>Waste</strong>, December<br />

2005, POST Note Number 252, www.parliament.uk/documents/upload/postpn252.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


shows improvements made in separate collection due both to improvements in<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> recycling services and also the introduction <strong>of</strong> charging in 1998. In the<br />

year 1998 a slight constraint on the overall growth <strong>of</strong> waste arisings may be<br />

observed, though this is barely discernible and could not be assumed to be<br />

statistically significant. However, separation <strong>of</strong> materials for recycling is much more<br />

apparent.<br />

Figure 8-1: Evolution <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> and Recycling in Ghent and Destelbergen<br />

Tonnes <strong>Waste</strong> Collected<br />

126<br />

120,000<br />

100,000<br />

80,000<br />

60,000<br />

40,000<br />

20,000<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999<br />

Year<br />

Others<br />

SDW (small dangerous waste)<br />

Wood<br />

Non-glass Packaging<br />

Electrical & Electronic Equpt.<br />

Metal<br />

Glass<br />

Garden green waste (containerpark)<br />

Separately Collected Biowaste (doorstep)<br />

Paper/hardboard<br />

Demolition waste<br />

Residual waste<br />

Source: Hogg, D. (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges. Referred to within this report<br />

as ‘the OECD charging review’. ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD.<br />

The review goes on to assess permutations <strong>of</strong> costs and benefits associated with<br />

these changes in waste production and separation, the results <strong>of</strong> which are shown in<br />

Figure 8-2. Because the scheme was introduced in a period where other changes<br />

were being made, the cost benefit is shown for cases where 25%, 50% and 100% <strong>of</strong><br />

the effects <strong>of</strong> the DVR scheme and the enhanced service are attributed to the DVR<br />

scheme. The net costs clearly depend upon the attribution. Attributing all the change<br />

to the charging scheme seems unrealistic and would lead to benefits (cost<br />

reductions) far greater than in the other schemes examined even though the effect on<br />

waste prevention is barely existent in this case. However, even where only 25% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> the change from 1997 to 1999 are attributed to the scheme, net social<br />

benefits (cost reductions) lie between €3 and €5 per household. It may be concluded<br />

from this not only that recycling leads to a positive balance <strong>of</strong> financial costs and<br />

environmental benefit (measured as monetised costs), but also that DVR charging<br />

itself can lead to outcomes where the benefits exceed the costs <strong>of</strong> the change.


Figure 8-2: Balance <strong>of</strong> Costs and Benefits <strong>of</strong> DVR scheme, Ghent and Destelbergen<br />

€ per Household<br />

127<br />

€ 5.00<br />

€ 0.00<br />

-€ 5.00<br />

-€ 10.00<br />

-€ 15.00<br />

-€ 20.00<br />

-€ 25.00<br />

-€ 30.00<br />

-€ 35.00<br />

-€ 40.00<br />

25% Effect Attributed to<br />

DVR Scheme<br />

Low Damage<br />

Costs<br />

High Damage<br />

Costs<br />

50% Effect Attributed to<br />

DVR Scheme<br />

Low Damage<br />

Costs<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

High Damage<br />

Costs<br />

100% Effect Attributed to<br />

DVR Scheme<br />

Low Damage<br />

Costs<br />

High Damage<br />

Costs<br />

Private Costs<br />

Net External Cost, Time Excluded<br />

Net External Cost, Time Included<br />

Balance <strong>of</strong> Costs and Benefits, Time Excluded<br />

Balance <strong>of</strong> Costs and Benefits, Time Included<br />

Source: Hogg, D. (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges. Referred to within this report<br />

as ‘the OECD charging review’. ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD.<br />

Within this study, there are few permutations where the system imposes net social<br />

costs. These are where a) a relatively small effect is attributed to the DVR scheme,<br />

and b) where the damage costs used are low (so benefits <strong>of</strong> avoided disposal and<br />

recycling are smaller). Such a scenario is shown on the left in Figure 8-2. The<br />

situation appears slightly worse where the costs <strong>of</strong> time are taken into account.<br />

However, even in the worst case the net social costs are <strong>of</strong> the order €2.00 per<br />

household.<br />

If, on the other hand, the DVR scheme is attributed with a more significant proportion<br />

<strong>of</strong> the change occurring between 1997 and 1999, then benefits may be as high as<br />

around €10 per household (50% effect attributable) rising to €21-34 if all the change<br />

occurring in the period is attributed to the DVR scheme.<br />

On balance, therefore, and based upon the effects <strong>of</strong> DVR schemes in similar<br />

situations elsewhere, it seems likely that the DVR charging scheme will have<br />

contributed to the generation <strong>of</strong> net social benefits. Indeed, perhaps the more<br />

important observation is that, as part <strong>of</strong> a package, the DVR scheme contributed<br />

(however significantly) to the generation <strong>of</strong> net social benefits <strong>of</strong> the order €20-30 per<br />

household. This is one <strong>of</strong> the key conclusions <strong>of</strong> the OECD charging review. 163<br />

163 D. Hogg (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges.<br />

ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD.


Although it may be demonstrated that DVR schemes (in the general case) can lead to<br />

positive outcomes, the specific impact <strong>of</strong> charging on households depends very much<br />

on the services in place and on the charging structure. The key issues are explored<br />

further in the following sections.<br />

8.5.2 General Themes on the Impact <strong>of</strong> Charging<br />

8.5.2.1 General Themes: <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

The evidence in the literature highlights varying results in different circumstances, but<br />

this is generally supportive <strong>of</strong> the waste prevention effects associated with pay-by-use<br />

schemes.<br />

It is fair to say that although evidence for increased recycling is very strong, not all<br />

studies report considerable quantities <strong>of</strong> waste ‘being prevented’; however, many<br />

report some effect. The quality <strong>of</strong> the evidence does not always allow detailed<br />

analysis since the scope <strong>of</strong> the investigation in the individual studies is not always<br />

clear. A large number <strong>of</strong> the studies identified in the Defra charging review focus only<br />

on the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste collected from households for disposal. Frequently, the<br />

headline figure reported is the ‘reduction in the quantity <strong>of</strong> material sent to landfill or<br />

incineration’.<br />

Where effects on total waste quantities are observed, it is not unusual for this figure<br />

to be in excess <strong>of</strong> 30%. In these instances, it is not always clear whether this is merely<br />

the effect <strong>of</strong> waste moving from one place to another (for example through ‘waste<br />

tourism’, illegal dumping, or through waste moving from domestic collection to<br />

commercial collection services or civic amenity sites). Gaining a clear understanding<br />

<strong>of</strong> the re-routing <strong>of</strong> waste is not straightforward.<br />

In general terms, associations between charging and waste prevention vary most<br />

greatly with the nature <strong>of</strong> the charging system as well as the nature <strong>of</strong> the collection<br />

systems before and after charging commences. Price clearly plays a role. To give a<br />

broad-brush figure, the Defra charging review reports that, depending on scheme<br />

types and charge levels, total waste quantities can fall by 10% and sometimes more<br />

due to pay-by-use systems.<br />

It is <strong>of</strong>ten difficult to isolate the impacts <strong>of</strong> a new charging system since they are<br />

normally accompanied by additional service changes. It is as important to appreciate<br />

the effect <strong>of</strong> the collection system on waste quantities as it is to understand the effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> any charge that is levied. The characteristics <strong>of</strong> garden waste generation are<br />

particularly important in the context <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use. Garden waste tends to increase in<br />

quantity when collected free <strong>of</strong> charge, but it can be dealt with reasonably<br />

comfortably in the home where collections are not free (or not in place at all). As such,<br />

the effects <strong>of</strong> charging (or not) for garden waste must be considered in the context <strong>of</strong><br />

the pre-existing collection arrangements. Much greater reductions tend to be<br />

achieved where the system in existence prior to charging included free garden waste<br />

collections, and where the charging system introduces charges for the garden waste<br />

element.<br />

A general shortcoming <strong>of</strong> most <strong>of</strong> the available case studies is that they tend to be<br />

based upon ‘before and after’ assessment as though waste quantities are static.<br />

Evidently, what ought to happen is that comparisons should be made against a<br />

128<br />

29/09/09


counterfactual. This type <strong>of</strong> approach is surprisingly rare in case studies, though some<br />

reports make comparisons between areas with, and areas without charging systems<br />

in place over a given period <strong>of</strong> time. Bisch<strong>of</strong> et. al., for example, compares areas with<br />

differential charging in Switzerland (where ‘residual’ waste reduced by 30%) with<br />

areas with a flat fee for disposal (where residual waste collected increased by up to<br />

13%). 164<br />

Even where studies look to assess overall waste reduction, there are some key<br />

caveats which need to be borne in mind when looking at much <strong>of</strong> the literature:<br />

129<br />

� First <strong>of</strong> all, and probably most importantly, many studies appear (it is not<br />

always made clear) to concentrate on door-to-door collections <strong>of</strong> waste and do<br />

not take a ‘whole system’ view (e.g. how the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste taken to Civic<br />

Amenity (CA) sites changes in the wake <strong>of</strong> the charging system’s<br />

implementation); and<br />

� Second, there is ongoing discussion as to the underlying cause <strong>of</strong> the<br />

‘disappearing waste’. Not all studies seek to explain the changes witnessed or<br />

reported.<br />

8.5.2.2 General Themes: Recycling<br />

The effects <strong>of</strong> charging on recycling are much more broadly recognised and widely<br />

documented, not least because the impact is much easier to measure and<br />

demonstrate in comparison to prevention.<br />

The trends demonstrated in the data in Figure 8-1 shown above for Ghent and<br />

Destelbergen are commonly observed following the introduction <strong>of</strong> charging schemes<br />

– material separated for recycling increasing significantly. Where prevention effects<br />

are strong, quantities recycled/composted may not increase so sharply, but the<br />

proportion recycled/composted clearly increases. Evidence discussed in the following<br />

sections goes on to qualify observed impacts on recycling in a range <strong>of</strong> situations.<br />

Three factors in particular have a strong influence on the impact <strong>of</strong> PAYT schemes:<br />

• The pre-scheme situation. Other things being equal, where there are lower<br />

levels <strong>of</strong> recycling prior to PAYT, the impact <strong>of</strong> charging may appear more<br />

significant;<br />

• Recycling system changes. The introduction <strong>of</strong> PAYT is <strong>of</strong>ten accompanied by<br />

improvements to recycling collection systems or centralised recycling facility<br />

provision. This makes the impacts <strong>of</strong> charging alone less easy to isolate;<br />

• The nature (and level) <strong>of</strong> charges. We investigate further in the following<br />

sections how different approaches to charging (pay by weight, pay by volume<br />

etc.) tend to perform in operation.<br />

Headline results from the VBWF in Korea have been impressive both in terms <strong>of</strong> the<br />

impact on waste prevention and recycling. As shown in Figure 8-3, total waste<br />

164 R. Bisch<strong>of</strong>, M. Chardonnens, M. Hugi, M. Textor, D. Lehmann, W. Siebert and K. Ammon (2003) La<br />

Taxe au Sac Vue par la Population et les Communes, Cahier de L’Environment 357, Berne: OFEPF<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


production has declined by 15% over the period following introduction <strong>of</strong> charging in<br />

1995. The amount <strong>of</strong> residual waste has declined significantly, while the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

waste recycled or composted has increased from approximately 15% in 1994 to<br />

nearly 50% in 2004. The quantity <strong>of</strong> waste recycled has increased by over 250%.<br />

Figure 8-3: Effects <strong>of</strong> Volume-based <strong>Waste</strong> Fee in Korea<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Qauntity (tonnes per day)<br />

130<br />

70,000<br />

60,000<br />

50,000<br />

40,000<br />

30,000<br />

20,000<br />

10,000<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004<br />

Year<br />

Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Recycled / Composted<br />

Source: Korea Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> Bulletin, Update Version <strong>of</strong> Issue 1, Volume 1, January 2006.<br />

Once again, however, the nature <strong>of</strong> waste collection service and recycling centre<br />

provision is important as this also influences performance. Other things being equal,<br />

a new charging system would be expected to encourage both prevention and<br />

recycling, but any accompanying new or expanded recycling services will lead to a<br />

change in performance whether charges on waste were applied or not.<br />

The following subsections attempt to draw together some individual lessons learnt on<br />

the effects <strong>of</strong> charging.<br />

8.5.3 Impact <strong>of</strong> Different Charging and Collection Structures<br />

A general assumption may be made that the order <strong>of</strong> ranking for both waste<br />

prevention and recycling is likely to be as follows, with the charging system achieving<br />

greatest effect listed first:<br />

� Weight (including biowaste) and frequency based (including biowaste);<br />

� Sack based (including biowaste);<br />

� Weight based (excl biowaste);<br />

� Frequency based;<br />

� Sack based (refuse only);


131<br />

� Bin-volume based (i.e. where households subscribe for a fixed period for a bin<br />

<strong>of</strong> a given size).<br />

The work by Tønning for the Danish EPA, summarized in Table 8-2, suggests that<br />

weight-based systems deliver the strongest effect both in terms <strong>of</strong> the reduction in<br />

collected waste and in terms <strong>of</strong> the increase in recycling. 165 We know that this study<br />

does not include ‘whole system’ wastes, however, so it could not be entirely ruled out<br />

that what is happening is that waste is simply moving through different routes in the<br />

system. Other details <strong>of</strong> the study – for example, the rates <strong>of</strong> home composting<br />

quoted – seem to imply that it is unlikely that this could account for all <strong>of</strong> the<br />

differences across schemes.<br />

Table 8-2: Performance <strong>of</strong> Different <strong>Waste</strong> Systems in Denmark<br />

Residual<br />

Residual<br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

(kg/inhab)<br />

(kg/inhab)<br />

Paper Paper and<br />

and<br />

Card<br />

Card<br />

Glass Glass Total<br />

Total<br />

(Increase (Increase in) in)<br />

in)<br />

Paper<br />

Paper<br />

Captures<br />

Captures<br />

(Increase (Increase in)<br />

in)<br />

Glass<br />

Glass<br />

Captures<br />

Captures<br />

Weight Weight-based<br />

Weight based 325 108 38 471 71% 87%<br />

Reference 729 67 34 830 41% 77%<br />

Difference -404 41 4 -359 (+30%) (+10%)<br />

Difference in % -55% 61% 12% -43% 43% 43% (+73%) (+13%)<br />

Volume Volume-based<br />

Volume based 552 104 40 696 61% 89%<br />

Reference 660 76 30 766 44% 67%<br />

Difference -108 28 10 -70 17% 22%<br />

Difference in % -16% 37% 33% -9% 9% (+39%) (+33%)<br />

Source: Tønning (2000)<br />

On the surface, the figures from this study look impressive. However, this study<br />

reminds us <strong>of</strong> an important lesson. In systems with kerbside recycling and<br />

composting schemes <strong>of</strong> narrow scope, the stated effects on total waste quantities<br />

may be exaggerated because more material is likely to be re-routed away from the<br />

doorstep collection system (to, for example, bring or CA site collections). If there are<br />

limited opportunities for segregation <strong>of</strong> materials presented by the kerbside<br />

collection, waste may be squeezed in other directions. This would be especially true<br />

where:<br />

� The recycling / composting service provision is more heavily oriented towards<br />

the provision <strong>of</strong> bring sites and CA sites; and<br />

� CA sites do not charge for the delivery <strong>of</strong> refuse-type waste.<br />

When assessing the literature, it is <strong>of</strong>ten difficult to know from the presentation <strong>of</strong><br />

data whether particular studies suffer from the same shortcomings.<br />

A study undertaken for VROM by KPMG (2001) attempted to understand the fate <strong>of</strong><br />

materials diverted from residual waste. In particular, it attempted to determine how<br />

much <strong>of</strong> the reduction in refuse was due to genuine waste reduction and how much<br />

due to evasive activities / illegal disposal. Comparative results across 4 different<br />

165 K. Tønning (2000) Fordele og ulemper ved gebyrdifferentierede indsamlingssystemer for<br />

husholdningsaffald, Teknologisk Institut, Miljoprojekt 576, Report for the Danish EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


‘DIFTAR’ system types were reported in an AOO (2001) publication and are shown in<br />

Figure 8-4. These results match the order <strong>of</strong> ranking for the impact on waste<br />

prevention as listed above. However, the study and its outcomes could be questioned<br />

on the basis that:<br />

132<br />

1. The municipalities using different systems may not be comparable in the<br />

manner suggested (there may be other factors compounding the analysis);<br />

and<br />

2. Possibly more significantly, it has not been possible for us to clarify whether<br />

this study addresses only door-to-door collections.<br />

Figure 8-4: Quantities <strong>of</strong> Separated <strong>Waste</strong> and Refuse by Charge System Type, 1999<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Collected (kg/inhabitant)<br />

500<br />

450<br />

400<br />

350<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

Source: AOO (2001)<br />

29/09/09<br />

Volume-based Volume and<br />

frequency-based<br />

Sack-based Weight-based Without DVR<br />

scheme<br />

Type <strong>of</strong> Scheme<br />

Vegetables, Fruit and Garden <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Textiles<br />

Glass<br />

Paper<br />

Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

The Dutch studies by Dijkgraaf and Gradus looked at data from the Netherlands<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Council (AOO) for 1998, 1999 and 2000 to estimate the effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> different charging schemes. 166 167 The later study suggested the following lending<br />

further support to the ranking <strong>of</strong> charging systems:<br />

� Weight-based schemes reduce total waste by 38%;<br />

166 E. Dijkgraaf and R. Gradus (2003) Cost Savings <strong>of</strong> Unit-Based Pricing <strong>of</strong> Household waste, the case<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Netherlands. Research Memorandum 0209, OCFEB, Erasmus University, Rotterdam.<br />

167 E. Dijkgraafand R. Gradus (2004) Cost Savings in Unit-based Pricing <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong>: The Case<br />

<strong>of</strong> The Netherlands, Resource and Energy Economics, Vol.26 (2004) 353-71 (note, the former paper is<br />

somewhat more extensive in its treatment).


133<br />

� Sack-based schemes with charges also placed on compostable waste reduce<br />

total waste by 36%. Where compostable waste is not charged for, the<br />

reduction in total waste is 14% (the difference in the two is reflected mainly in<br />

the quantity <strong>of</strong> material collected separately from the kerbside);<br />

� The frequency based system delivers a reduction in total waste <strong>of</strong> 21%; and<br />

� The volume based bin system delivers a reduction in total waste <strong>of</strong> 6%.<br />

This data suggests that the approach to the charging <strong>of</strong> garden waste is also<br />

important. It should be noted that these effects were achieved at different price<br />

levels. However, the same work includes estimates <strong>of</strong> elasticities as shown in Table<br />

8-3. These high results are probably indicative <strong>of</strong> the Netherlands experience where<br />

garden waste had previously been collected free <strong>of</strong> charge (so giving greater scope for<br />

reduction).<br />

Table 8-3: Estimated Price Elasticities under Different Charging Schemes<br />

Price Price Total Total Unsorted Unsorted Compos Compostable<br />

Compos table Recyclable<br />

Recyclable<br />

Standard model<br />

Weight 4.39 -0.47 -0.67 -0.92 0.16<br />

Bag, refuse and<br />

compostable<br />

2.02 -0.43 -0.66 -0.97 0.25<br />

Bag, refuse 2.15 -0.14 -0.71 0.29 0.14<br />

Frequency 3.91 -0.22 -0.28 -0.40 0.08<br />

Volume<br />

Model with environmental<br />

activism<br />

1.94 -0.06 -0.12 0.01 0.01<br />

Weight 4.39 -0.40 -0.53 -0.81 0.12<br />

Bag, refuse and<br />

compostable<br />

2.02 -0.36 -0.51 -0.85 0.20<br />

Bag, refuse 2.15 -0.07 -0.58 0.40 0.09<br />

Frequency 3.91 -0.16 -0.16 -0.31 0.04<br />

Volume 1.94 -0.00 0.01 0.09 -0.03<br />

Source: Dijkgraaf, E., and Gradus, R. (2003) Cost Savings <strong>of</strong> Unit-Based Pricing <strong>of</strong> Household waste,<br />

the case <strong>of</strong> the Netherlands. Rotterdam: OCFEB<br />

The work by Dijkgraaf and Gradus is <strong>of</strong> particular interest in the evaluation <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental effectiveness <strong>of</strong> PAYT systems. In their studies they attempted an<br />

extensive cost-benefit analysis <strong>of</strong> DVR charging systems, noting:<br />

“From a welfare point <strong>of</strong> view a number <strong>of</strong> effects are important with respect<br />

to the evaluation <strong>of</strong> unit-based pricing systems:<br />

1. The change in collection costs due to the effect on the collected<br />

quantity.<br />

2. The change in treatment costs due to the effect on the collected<br />

quantity.<br />

3. The change in administrative costs due to the introduction and<br />

maintenance <strong>of</strong> the unit-based pricing system.<br />

4. The social costs <strong>of</strong> extra illegal dumping due to the introduction <strong>of</strong> unitbased<br />

pricing system.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


134<br />

29/09/09<br />

[…] As we are interested in the welfare effects <strong>of</strong> the different systems not<br />

only the out <strong>of</strong> pocket costs (private costs) are important, but also the effects<br />

on the environment <strong>of</strong> collection and treatment.”<br />

A thorough review <strong>of</strong> this work is given in the OECD charging review but a summary <strong>of</strong><br />

the details and findings is useful here. The system examined was based entirely on<br />

bring sites where the collection <strong>of</strong> dry recyclables (GPT, or glass, paper and textiles)<br />

was concerned. A door-to-door collection for refuse and for VFG (vegetable, fruit and<br />

garden) waste was in place. An important feature <strong>of</strong> the study was the attempt to<br />

model different DVR charging systems.<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> the analysis are shown in Table 8-4. One assumes that the<br />

presentation is based upon costs per household (the study is not absolutely clear on<br />

this). The suggestion is clearly that weight and sack based schemes (and to a lesser<br />

extent volume or volume and frequency based schemes) deliver both private cost<br />

savings and environmental improvement (relative to a flat rate fee baseline).<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the observations regarding net costs and benefits are important in the<br />

context <strong>of</strong> changes in waste arisings and recycling:<br />

“It should be noticed that the weight-based and the bag-based system<br />

decrease the amount <strong>of</strong> solid waste with large environmental costs<br />

substantially and increase the amount <strong>of</strong> recyclable waste with high<br />

environmental benefits also substantially. From the view <strong>of</strong> private costs the<br />

weight-based system performs better than the other systems. The reason for<br />

this is the higher savings on collected waste. Therefore, in social terms the<br />

weight-based system performs slightly better than the bag-based system.” 168<br />

In a subsequent paper, the authors appear to have revised their views somewhat.<br />

They conclude:<br />

“We find that the weight- and bag-based pricing systems perform far better<br />

than the frequency- and volume-based pricing systems. The bag-based system<br />

seems to be the best option, as its effects are comparable to those <strong>of</strong> the<br />

weight-based system and yet its administrative costs are far lower.” 169<br />

The principle reason for this appears to be appreciation <strong>of</strong> the administrative costs <strong>of</strong><br />

running the schemes. The later study suggests these are €6.86 per inhabitant for a<br />

weight-based scheme and €3.18 for a bag-based scheme. 170<br />

168 E. Dijkgraaf and R. Gradus (2003) Cost Savings <strong>of</strong> Unit-Based Pricing <strong>of</strong> Household waste, the case<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Netherlands. Research Memorandum 0209, OCFEB, Erasmus University, Rotterdam.<br />

169 E. Dijkgraafand R. Gradus (2004) Cost Savings in Unit-based Pricing <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong>: The Case<br />

<strong>of</strong> The Netherlands, Resource and Energy Economics, Vol.26 (2004) 353-71 (note, the former paper is<br />

somewhat more extensive in its treatment).<br />

170 These figures are taken from VROM (1997).


Table 8-4: Costs under Flat Rate Fees and Changes in Costs Under Different Charging<br />

Schemes<br />

135<br />

Costs Costs (interpreted (interpreted to be<br />

€ € per per household)<br />

household)<br />

Flat Flat rate<br />

rate<br />

(level)<br />

(level)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Weight<br />

Weight<br />

(change)<br />

(change)<br />

Bag<br />

Bag<br />

(change)<br />

(change)<br />

Vol. Vol. and and and Freq.<br />

Freq.<br />

(change)<br />

(change)<br />

Volume<br />

Volume<br />

(change)<br />

(change)<br />

Total Total private private costs costs<br />

45 -14 -12 -6 +1<br />

Total Total environmental environmental costs costs<br />

-12 -6 -6 -3 -0<br />

Total Total social social costs costs<br />

33 -20 -18 -9 +0<br />

Source: Dijkgraaf and Gradus (2003)<br />

8.5.4 The Movement <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> and Impact <strong>of</strong> Changes in System<br />

Infrastructure<br />

A report in the Netherlands by Proietti cites a particular study conducted for the VROM<br />

(The Netherlands Ministry <strong>of</strong> Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment) by<br />

KPMG in 1995-1996. 171 This reported a 12 to 30% reduction in household refuse<br />

owing to DIFTAR schemes, including:<br />

� 6 to 8% due to improved sorting (for recycling) by householders;<br />

� 3 to 10% due to ‘unintended activity’; and<br />

� 3 to 12% due to genuine prevention measures (calculated).<br />

This indicates that PAYT systems ‘squeeze’ waste in a number <strong>of</strong> directions.<br />

In France, a recent study examined the differences between 4 municipalities without<br />

incentive based schemes, and six who had implemented them. 172 Summarised<br />

results are available in Table 2 within the Defra Charging <strong>Review</strong>. Although, more<br />

analysis would be required to see whether total waste quantities were actually<br />

increasing or falling under the schemes, the study does reveal some interesting<br />

trends. Generally, rates <strong>of</strong> recycling were higher and residual waste per inhabitant<br />

was on the decline in those areas with incentive based systems in place. The weakest<br />

impact appears to have been in the volume based bin system. Crucially, the data also<br />

highlights that there were changes in the proportion <strong>of</strong> waste managed through bulky<br />

waste and CA-site type locations. The study suggests, however, that in several cases<br />

171 Stefano Proietti (2000), The Application <strong>of</strong> local Taxes and Fees for the Collection <strong>of</strong> Household<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>: Local Authority Jurisdiction and Practice in Europe, Report for the Association <strong>of</strong> Cities for<br />

Recycling, Brussels: ACR.<br />

172 Olivier Arnold, Damien George, Rachel Bauudry, Thomas Gaudin, Eve Toleedano d’Amorce (2005)<br />

Causes et Effets du passage de la TEOM a la REOM, Final Report, Ministere de L’Ecologie et du<br />

Developpement Durable, August 2005.


the infrastructure in this regard was improved over the period drawing more material<br />

through this route.<br />

The literature most clearly shows that charging for household waste moves material<br />

from refuse to kerbside recycling. Beyond this however, changes in flows <strong>of</strong> material<br />

caused by charging schemes are generally poorly understood. It is fair to assume that<br />

if constraints are placed on one part <strong>of</strong> the waste management system, then material<br />

has a habit <strong>of</strong> flowing onto other parts <strong>of</strong> the system. In an original case study we<br />

carried out in Schweinfurt, the director <strong>of</strong> the service was particularly keen to<br />

understand where the waste had gone. 173 Even after exploring all <strong>of</strong> the following,<br />

one-sixth <strong>of</strong> the reduction in residual waste remained unexplained:<br />

136<br />

� Quantities <strong>of</strong> recycled material, before and after;<br />

� Composition <strong>of</strong> residual waste before and after;<br />

� Rates <strong>of</strong> home composting, before and after;<br />

� Possible causes <strong>of</strong> a reduction in the amount <strong>of</strong> inert building / DIY waste<br />

generated;<br />

� Change in the use <strong>of</strong> nappies from disposables to re-usables;<br />

� Consumer choices;<br />

� Burning <strong>of</strong> waste by households (regarding this issue, the county sought<br />

information from chimney sweeps).<br />

� Householders taking their waste to their place <strong>of</strong> work;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> being flushed into sewers (down toilets);<br />

� Fly-tipping.<br />

Clearly, this is a complex issue, and measuring any one <strong>of</strong> these in a manner which<br />

gives confidence is not straightforward. The list above may not tell the whole story.<br />

Discussions with a representative from the Treviso area <strong>of</strong> Italy, where waste was<br />

reduced by more than 10%, suggested that there are three main avenues through<br />

which waste quantities were reduced following charging: 174<br />

� Increases in home composting;<br />

� Movement <strong>of</strong> commercial waste into the right avenues; and<br />

� Genuine waste prevention.<br />

Another issue which may be important in some contexts is that <strong>of</strong> waste tourism. In a<br />

study for the OECD, in the case <strong>of</strong> the Spanish municipality <strong>of</strong> Torrelles de Llobregat,<br />

we estimated that the phenomenon might account for 15% <strong>of</strong> the observed reduction<br />

in waste quantities. 175 The municipality would have been particularly likely to give rise<br />

173 Eunomia (2003) To Charge or Not to Charge? Final report to IWM (EB).<br />

174 Personal communication, Paolo Conto, Consorzio Intercommunale Priula.<br />

175 D. Hogg (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges. Referred to within the text <strong>of</strong> this<br />

report as ‘the OECD charging review’. ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD.<br />

29/09/09


to this type <strong>of</strong> abuse given a) its small size; and b) the fact that no other municipality<br />

in Catalunya (or Spain) was implementing such charges. Other things being equal,<br />

one would expect problems <strong>of</strong> waste tourism to be greater in such situations (the<br />

opportunity is greater and the benefit is maximised), and much reduced where<br />

charging is implemented over large, contiguous areas.<br />

It has been suggested that one <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> household waste charging is that it<br />

leads to commercial waste that is otherwise being collected through the household<br />

system being shifted into the “correct” channels (so that households are not crosssubsidising<br />

small businesses).<br />

8.5.5 Specific Impacts on Organic <strong>Waste</strong> (Due to Changes in Collection<br />

Systems)<br />

In many instances, the key waste prevention measure observed tends to be due to<br />

home composting. This happens most <strong>of</strong> all:<br />

137<br />

� For perhaps obvious reasons, where charges are levied on biowaste sacks /<br />

bins as well as refuse sacks / bins. This is becoming a widespread<br />

phenomenon in Germany, Austria and Belgium; or<br />

� Where the only biowaste collection is for kitchen waste, and where support is<br />

<strong>of</strong>fered for home composting (this occurs in Italy).<br />

The large reduction in collected waste seen in the Netherlands, for instance may be<br />

strongly related to the garden waste collection previously in existence. Such a<br />

prevention effect may not be expected where no such collection has ever been in<br />

place. The case <strong>of</strong> Comuni dei Navigli in Italy, as documented in the IWM charging<br />

review, involved a sack-based system where the previous approach to organic wastes<br />

was collection <strong>of</strong> kitchen waste, with garden waste not included in the collection<br />

system. 176 The study indicated little by way <strong>of</strong> reduction in waste quantities. Given<br />

that in most studies, a key contribution to waste prevention appears to come through<br />

the increased uptake and intensity <strong>of</strong> home composting, the likelihood that relatively<br />

little garden waste was previously being collected suggests that the ‘opportunity’ for<br />

waste prevention through this avenue would have been reduced.<br />

This indicates a possible element <strong>of</strong> ‘path-dependence’ in the measured<br />

effectiveness <strong>of</strong> charging systems as regards waste prevention.<br />

8.5.6 Factors That Can Reduce the Impact <strong>of</strong> Charging on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Prevention<br />

The IWM charging review showed pay-by-use can have significant impacts on waste<br />

prevention. For example a scheme in Landkreis Schweinfurt, Germany delivered a<br />

reduction in total waste collected <strong>of</strong> around 28% <strong>of</strong> the pre-scheme quantity (using a<br />

volume, frequency and weight based scheme including charges for garden waste);<br />

this percentage is reduced somewhat if ‘expectation effects’ (household clear outs<br />

176 Eunomia (2003) To Charge or Not to Charge? Final report to IWM (EB). Referred to within the text <strong>of</strong><br />

this report as ‘the IWM charging review’.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


efore the onset <strong>of</strong> charging) are accounted for. Additionally, a scheme in the Treviso<br />

2 area <strong>of</strong> Italy showed a reduction <strong>of</strong> around 12% was achieved through a frequency<br />

based scheme.<br />

The evidence (and logic) would suggest that a restriction on the volume <strong>of</strong> waste does<br />

not necessarily translate into a reduction on the weight <strong>of</strong> waste disposed. The IWM<br />

charging review revealed that in Nijmegen (a sack-based scheme), quantities did not<br />

change significantly. In this case, the recycling infrastructure was poor, and it may be<br />

that households merely crammed their sacks more than previously.<br />

Table 8-5 shows the results <strong>of</strong> a study carried out in 2002 by Skumatz. 177 This used<br />

two approaches to estimate the source reduction effects <strong>of</strong> charging schemes in the<br />

United States. These effects are not as great as one finds in many cases where<br />

charging schemes are implemented in Europe. Specifically, many weight-based and<br />

frequency-based schemes report much higher reductions in waste collected. Skumatz<br />

reported that no full-scale weight-based programmes were operating in the USA. Binvolume<br />

or tagged sack schemes were in widespread operation (for example Seattle,<br />

San Francisco).<br />

Table 8-5: Source Reduction Estimates from Variable-rate <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal<br />

Programmes in the US (combination <strong>of</strong> bin-volume and paid sack (volume) schemes)<br />

Community Community Compari Comparison<br />

Compari son<br />

Method<br />

Method<br />

Time Time Series Series Method Method<br />

Method<br />

Total effect <strong>of</strong> variable-rate programme 16 % 17.3%<br />

Minus recycling effect for variable rates 5-6% 6.9%<br />

Minus yard-waste effect for variable rates 4-5% 4.6%<br />

Leaves estimate <strong>of</strong> source-reduction effect<br />

5-7% from 5.8% from source<br />

attributable to variable rate programs<br />

source reduction<br />

reduction<br />

Source: SERA (2000) Measuring Source Reduction: Pay as you Throw / Variable Rates as an Example,<br />

Seattle: Skumatz Economic Research Associates.<br />

We would consider that, excluding flat fee systems, subscription-based volume<br />

related charging systems, where households choose a bin size for use over a year or<br />

longer, have the lowest impact in terms <strong>of</strong> waste prevention.<br />

8.5.7 Price Responsiveness<br />

Fee levels can have a big impact on the success, or otherwise, <strong>of</strong> a charging scheme.<br />

We have mentioned above that it is important to set charge differentials broad<br />

enough to encourage positive behaviour, but not so broad (or high) that illegal<br />

behaviour (see Section 8.11 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes) is encouraged.<br />

Work has been done on the effect <strong>of</strong> different charge levels on the quantities <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

disposed. A study for OVAM (Gellynck and Verhelst, 2005) conducted regression<br />

analysis on 306 municipalities with what appears to be good quality data – including<br />

collections from containerparks, etc. The aim was to develop an equation to describe<br />

177 L. Skumatz (2002) Variable-Rate or “Pay As You Throw” <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Answers to Frequently<br />

Asked Questions, Los Angeles: Reason Foundation.<br />

138<br />

29/09/09


the effect <strong>of</strong> certain variables on residual waste per inhabitant. The equation<br />

developed suggests that for every additional Euro paid (on a variable rate) for residual<br />

waste, quantities fall by around 400g per inhabitant. The average payment for<br />

residual waste in Flanders is around €60-70 per household per year, giving a net<br />

reduction <strong>of</strong> the order 24-28 kg per inhabitant per year (with additional effects<br />

potentially attributable to the proportion <strong>of</strong> costs covered through direct means). The<br />

Flemish experience is significant in that the country has set a target for residual<br />

waste to be no more than 150kg per inhabitant across the whole region. The<br />

equation does not give evidence <strong>of</strong> waste prevention per se. It does, however, give<br />

some indication <strong>of</strong> the combined effect <strong>of</strong> recycling and waste prevention at the level<br />

<strong>of</strong> the individual. It does so taking into account a range <strong>of</strong> variables including personal<br />

income per inhabitant, collection frequencies, and whether organic wastes are<br />

collected.<br />

A demonstration <strong>of</strong> the price responsiveness <strong>of</strong> residual waste disposal to the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

sacks is given in Figure 8-5. The extensive literature review <strong>of</strong> price elasticities (ε)<br />

under different charging schemes summarised within the Defra charging review is<br />

reproduced here in Table 8-6. This table groups studies according to the type <strong>of</strong><br />

scheme used (with the exception <strong>of</strong> those looking at various scheme types). It can be<br />

seen that there is a tendency for the elasticity (for refuse quantities) to increase<br />

moving through volume-based, to sack-based to weight-based schemes. This ranking<br />

reinforces trends demonstrated in the Dijkgraaf and Gradus work shown in Table 8-3<br />

in Section 8.5.3 above.<br />

Figure 8-5: Plot <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong> per Inhabitant (y-axis) Against Sack Price (x-axis) for<br />

Flemish Schemes<br />

Source: Hogg, D., Wilson, D., Gibbs, A., Astley, M., Papineschi, J. (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong><br />

Household Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra.<br />

139<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 8-6: Empirical Estimates <strong>of</strong> the Effect <strong>of</strong> Unit-pricing<br />

140<br />

29/09/09<br />

Study Study Study<br />

Data<br />

Data<br />

Wertz (1976)<br />

Jenkins (1993)<br />

Hong et al.<br />

(1993)<br />

Strathman et al.<br />

(1995)<br />

Van Houtven and<br />

Morris (1999)<br />

Van Houtven and<br />

Morris (1999)<br />

Reschovsky and<br />

Stone (1994)<br />

Fullerton and<br />

Kinnaman (1996)<br />

Podolsky and<br />

Spiegel (1998)<br />

Kinnaman and<br />

Fullerton (1997)<br />

Van Houtven and<br />

Morris (1999)<br />

Van Houtven and<br />

Morris (1999)<br />

Hong (1999)<br />

Linderh<strong>of</strong> et al<br />

(2001)<br />

Linderh<strong>of</strong> et al<br />

(2001)<br />

Miranda et al.<br />

(1994)<br />

Callan and<br />

Thomas (1997)<br />

Seguino et al.<br />

(1995)<br />

Volume based - Compares subscription<br />

program in San Francisco with flat fees<br />

imposed by “all urban areas”<br />

Volume-based - Panel <strong>of</strong> 14 cities (10 with<br />

user fees) over 1980-88<br />

Volume based - 1990 survey <strong>of</strong> 4,306<br />

households in and around Portland,<br />

Oregon.<br />

Volume-based - Seven year (1984-1991)<br />

time series in Portland, OR<br />

Change Change in<br />

in<br />

Refuse<br />

Refuse<br />

ε = -0.15<br />

ε = -0.12<br />

No significant<br />

impact<br />

ε = -0.11<br />

Volume (household survey data) ε = -0.10<br />

Volume (municipality data) < 0<br />

Sack-based - 1992 mail survey <strong>of</strong> 1,422<br />

households in and around Ithaca, NY.<br />

Sack-based - Two-period panel <strong>of</strong> 75<br />

households in 1992<br />

Sack-based - 1992 cross-section <strong>of</strong> 159<br />

municipalities in NJ, 12 with unit-pricing<br />

Sack-based - 1991 cross-section <strong>of</strong> 959<br />

towns across the U. S., 114 with unitpricing<br />

ε = -0.076<br />

(weight)<br />

ε = -0.226<br />

(volume)<br />

ε = -0.39<br />

ε = -0.19<br />

ε = -0.28<br />

Sack-based (household survey data) ε = -0.26<br />

Sack-based (municipality data) ε = -0.19<br />

Sack-based – National data from Korean<br />

volume based waste fee<br />

Weight-based – compostable waste<br />

(Oostzaan, Netherlands)<br />

Weight-based - residual waste (Oostzaan,<br />

Netherlands)<br />

Various - Panel <strong>of</strong> 21 cities over 18<br />

months beginning in 1990<br />

Various (bag, tag, volume) - 1994 crosssection<br />

<strong>of</strong> 324 towns in MA, 55 with unit-<br />

pricing programs<br />

1993-1994 cross section <strong>of</strong> 60 towns in<br />

Maine, 29 with unit-pricing<br />

ε = -0.15<br />

ε = -1.39<br />

ε = -0.34<br />

17%-74%<br />

reduction in<br />

garbage<br />

56% decrease<br />

Change Change in<br />

in<br />

Recycling<br />

Recycling<br />

Unspecified<br />

positive<br />

relationship<br />

No significant<br />

impact<br />

Cross-price<br />

elasticity is 0.073<br />

ε = 0.23<br />

ε = 0.22<br />

Average increase<br />

<strong>of</strong> 128%<br />

Source: Hogg, D., Wilson, D., Gibbs, A., Astley, M., Papineschi, J. (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong><br />

Household Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra.<br />

8.5.8 Further Summarised Evidence Concerning <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

ε = -0.07<br />

The review in the appendices <strong>of</strong> the Defra charging review highlights many other<br />

individual case studies where reductions in arisings are reported. Although prevention


effects are not always verifiable in the ‘whole system’ sense, they are at least<br />

suggestive <strong>of</strong> some degree <strong>of</strong> waste prevention in the case <strong>of</strong> some systems.<br />

On balance, one might say the literature <strong>of</strong>fers support for the prevention effects <strong>of</strong><br />

charging, but that the quality <strong>of</strong> evidence is somewhat variable, so that the accuracy<br />

<strong>of</strong> the reported effects is not what it might be. It would be reasonable to assume,<br />

however, that reported effects in schemes where the scope and convenience <strong>of</strong> the<br />

kerbside collection service is extremely good – as it is in Flanders, for example – will<br />

tend to give a more accurate picture than in those where the collection service is less<br />

convenient, and where it is clear that the focus is on waste collected from the<br />

doorstep only. In these systems, rather like a balloon, waste has greater potential to<br />

be ‘squeezed’ from one part <strong>of</strong> the management system (doorstep collection) to<br />

another (illegal dumping, bring sites, CA sites, etc.).<br />

A final point worth making is that the prevention impacts <strong>of</strong> charging systems are<br />

difficult to define in absolute terms due to the compounding complication <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

growth. As indicated above there tend to be limited opportunities to reference to a<br />

satisfactory counterfactual; instead, measurements <strong>of</strong> ‘prevention’ tend to be based<br />

on ‘before’ and ‘after’ comparisons <strong>of</strong> waste arisings. The true impact, therefore, can<br />

be somewhat obscured by waste growth, which can vary widely on a yearly basis due<br />

to other factors besides (not least changes in the collection systems as discussed<br />

above). Any data based on annual arising figures needs to be considered within the<br />

context that waste prevention equates not just to ‘a reduction in waste’ but a<br />

‘reduction in waste growth’.<br />

8.5.9 Further Summarised Evidence Concerning Recycling<br />

In a large number <strong>of</strong> studies in the literature, the demonstrable effect <strong>of</strong> PAYT is to<br />

increase the proportion <strong>of</strong> waste being recycled and composted, as opposed to<br />

increase the quantity.<br />

A widely quoted meta-study is that <strong>of</strong> Kinnaman and Fullerton who used communitylevel<br />

data on aggregate recycling quantities. 178 179 Correcting for endogenous local<br />

policy choices, they suggest that a unit pricing program has an insignificant effect on<br />

recycling while the presence <strong>of</strong> a kerbside recycling program has a positive and<br />

significant effect. Yet the same work includes model specifications for the quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

residual waste. This shows the annual weight <strong>of</strong> garbage to be higher (under the<br />

endogenous choice model) where kerbside recycling systems only are in place. Where<br />

charging systems are also in place, the effect is to strongly reduce residual waste<br />

quantities in a highly significant manner. In this context, the suggestion that recycled<br />

quantities are not heavily affected by charging schemes is not a rejection <strong>of</strong> the<br />

effectiveness <strong>of</strong> charging schemes in increasing the intensity <strong>of</strong> recycling (as<br />

measured by capture rates). What the modelling seems to suggest (but what the<br />

178 Thomas Kinnaman and Don Fullerton (1997) Garbage and Recycling in Communities with Curbside<br />

recycling and Unit-pricing, NBER Working Paper 6021; NBER, Massachussetts, Cambridge.<br />

179 Thomas Kinnaman and Don Fullerton (1998) Garbage and Recycling with Endogenous Local <strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

Mimeo, 1998.<br />

141<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


authors do not point out) is that the same quantity <strong>of</strong> material appears to be being<br />

recycled from a smaller total amount. In other words, the recycling rate would have<br />

increased (and residual waste would have fallen). Taken together, the modelling<br />

seems, subject to caveats, to support (rather than oppose) the view that charging<br />

schemes encourage waste prevention and separation for recycling, though the<br />

authors also highlight the potential for illegal dumping.<br />

This is not the only econometric meta-study to gloss over potentially important details<br />

<strong>of</strong> scheme design. Arguably, in specific case studies, if charging systems are<br />

introduced where all else remains the same from the householder’s perspective (<strong>of</strong><br />

the system), then before and after cases are likely to provide more reliable evidence.<br />

Here, the evidence is rather more compelling (and the weight <strong>of</strong> evidence makes the<br />

econometric studies seem out <strong>of</strong> kilter with empirical experience). A thorough<br />

literature review is given in Appendix 1 <strong>of</strong> the Defra charging report. Individual studies<br />

quote PBU leading to anywhere from a zero increase in quantities recycled (but<br />

normally a reduction in residual waste, thereby implying an increase in the proportion<br />

captured), to increases in recycling <strong>of</strong> 5–6 percent (see Table 8-5), to increases in the<br />

weight <strong>of</strong> material recycled <strong>of</strong> between 32% and 59% - this specific case being for<br />

cities that did not change their recycling program with the introduction <strong>of</strong> PBU. 180<br />

The Appendix to the Defra charging report shows a large number <strong>of</strong> results, very few<br />

<strong>of</strong> which lead to no change in the level <strong>of</strong> recycling following the introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

charging systems. Two such examples are given in the IWM charging review - the<br />

cases <strong>of</strong> Comuni dei Navigli and in Nijmegen. In the former, the small areas<br />

concerned were already achieving high recycling rates and the ‘head room’ for<br />

improvement may have been limited. In Nijmegen, the collection system was not<br />

especially comprehensive. Much emphasis was placed upon the development <strong>of</strong> a<br />

new major bring recycling centre in the city, and this appears to have been as, if not<br />

more, important than the charging system itself in the development <strong>of</strong> services to<br />

households. Evidently, if this hypothesis is correct, one would expect to see the<br />

greatest impacts being experienced at the major bring system.<br />

The literature is less able to show differing levels <strong>of</strong> impact from the different<br />

approaches to charging. A problem here is that relatively few studies assess capture<br />

rates. The work by Tønning (see Table 8-2) indicates that captures in weight-based<br />

systems lead to greater increases in captures <strong>of</strong> paper, whilst volume based systems<br />

are more successful in increasing captures <strong>of</strong> glass. It is not clear how the capture<br />

rates were determined in the study (and in particular, how pre- and post-scheme<br />

compositions were estimated).<br />

180 Marie Lynn Miranda and Sharon LaPalme (1997) Unit Pricing <strong>of</strong> Residential solid <strong>Waste</strong>: A<br />

Preliminary Analysis <strong>of</strong> 212 U.S. Communities, June 4, 1997, Nicholas School <strong>of</strong> the Environment,<br />

Duke University.<br />

142<br />

29/09/09


A French study (results shown in Figure 8-6) by Sebastien in 2005 tentatively notes<br />

that weight-based systems have a stronger effect than sack-based schemes: 181<br />

143<br />

The key point is that that the use <strong>of</strong> on-vehicle weighing is the most effective<br />

method to reduce the quantity <strong>of</strong> residual waste and the total quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

waste, like improving the rate <strong>of</strong> sorting (voluntary glass and contributions). It<br />

is however advisable to handle these data with precaution because they were<br />

comparisons between different cities, and not the comparisons within the<br />

same city where two different modes <strong>of</strong> tariffing would have been used.<br />

Figure 8-6: Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Different Charging Schemes<br />

Source: Sebastien, G. (2005) La tarification des ordures ménagères liée à la quantité de déchets :<br />

enseignements des expériences européennes et perspectives pour la France, Report for ADEME.<br />

In summary, there is very little evidence to support a ranking in terms <strong>of</strong> the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

different charging systems on captures <strong>of</strong> recyclables, and indeed, one might argue<br />

that what seems more likely is that combinations <strong>of</strong> collection and charging systems<br />

are likely to deliver different results. On the basis <strong>of</strong> information which is available,<br />

more analysis could help to provide comparative changes in captures. However, this<br />

would, in turn, require some pre- and post-scheme composition analysis, and it is rare<br />

to find this for authorities implementing any scheme change, let alone one involving<br />

charging.<br />

Charging schemes invariably increase the proportion <strong>of</strong> material recycled through<br />

waste prevention combined with a nominal uplift in the percentage capture <strong>of</strong><br />

recyclable material. Furthermore, although significantly dependant on the pre- and<br />

post-scheme collection systems, as well as the charging system used, many studies<br />

demonstrate overall increases in the quantities <strong>of</strong> material recycled.<br />

181 Galliano Sebastien (2005) La tarification des ordures ménagères liée à la quantité de déchets :<br />

enseignements des expériences européennes et perspectives pour la France, Report for ADEME,<br />

January 2005.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


8.5.10 Climate Change Assessment <strong>of</strong> the Impacts <strong>of</strong> Variable Charging<br />

The review given so far within this section has demonstrated that charging systems<br />

have the effect <strong>of</strong> increasing recycling and composting, as well as preventing the<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> some wastes in the first place. Analysis we conducted as part <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Defra charging report estimated the climate change-related benefits from pay-by-use<br />

systems being applied in England using data on the benefits associated with recycling<br />

from three different sources: 182<br />

144<br />

� Using research undertaken by ERM, Defra has supplied ‘low’ and ‘high’<br />

estimates <strong>of</strong> the benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling different materials;<br />

� Using work undertaken on behalf <strong>of</strong> WRAP; and<br />

� Using our own review <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> the literature, with specific figures were<br />

chosen for specific materials.<br />

Figure 8-7 shows the benefits (for the situation in which 62% <strong>of</strong> England households<br />

are assumed to be on charging schemes) from recycling under the different scenarios<br />

alongside what would have happened if the same materials had been treated through<br />

energy from waste (EfW) incineration, or landfill. For the ERM Low and High<br />

Scenarios, the ERM low and high benefits from EfW incineration and landfill<br />

respectively were used. For the Eunomia Scenarios, the average <strong>of</strong> ERM’s high and<br />

low benefits was used.<br />

The situation is shown in tabular form in Table 8-7, which also includes benefits from<br />

the recycling <strong>of</strong> dry materials estimated using figures from WRAP’s recent review <strong>of</strong><br />

life-cycle studies in the field. The first row <strong>of</strong> figures shows the saving from recycling.<br />

The second row shows what savings would have occurred had the material been<br />

recovered as residual waste or disposed <strong>of</strong> (through EfW incineration or landfill). The<br />

final row shows the net effect <strong>of</strong> switching from the disposal route to the recycling<br />

route, and is calculated by subtracting the figure in the second row from the figure in<br />

the first.<br />

These benefits, expressed in terms <strong>of</strong> savings <strong>of</strong> CO2, were converted to a monetary<br />

figure. The savings were estimated as shown in Table 8-8. The savings were<br />

estimated at between £4-£15 million where the alternative disposal route is assumed<br />

to be EfW, and £8-24 million where the waste would have been landfilled (which<br />

seems more likely in the current context).<br />

It is important to note that these savings relate only to the additional recycling. There<br />

are also benefits associated with waste prevention. These are more difficult to<br />

calculate as the benefits rely on prior knowledge as to the average ‘recycled material<br />

content’ <strong>of</strong> each <strong>of</strong> the materials which are being ‘prevented’ from arising as waste. It<br />

is worth pointing out, however, that the additional recycling is far smaller in total<br />

quantity than the waste prevention (the latter is approximately four times the former).<br />

182 D. Hogg, D. Wilson, A. Gibbs, M. Astley and J. Papineschi (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong> Household<br />

Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra. Referred to within the text <strong>of</strong> this report as ‘the<br />

Defra charging review’.<br />

29/09/09


Therefore, it would seem reasonable to assume that the benefits would most likely be<br />

at least <strong>of</strong> the same order as for the recycling. Indeed, one would expect them to be<br />

higher.<br />

Figure 8-7: GHG-related Impacts <strong>of</strong> Recycling Associated with Charging Schemes and<br />

Avoided Disposal (all figures expressed as savings in tonnes CO2 equivalent)<br />

Tonnes <strong>of</strong> CO2 (equ) Saved in Process<br />

145<br />

1,200,000<br />

1,000,000<br />

800,000<br />

600,000<br />

400,000<br />

200,000<br />

0<br />

-200,000<br />

-400,000<br />

-600,000<br />

Eunomia, EfW ERM Low, EfW ERM High, EfW Eunomia, Landfill ERM Low, Landfill ERM High, Landfill<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Scenario<br />

Source: Hogg, D., Wilson, D., Gibbs, A., Astley, M., Papineschi, J. (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong><br />

Household Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra.<br />

Recycling Total<br />

Disposal Total<br />

Table 8-7: Impacts <strong>of</strong> Additional Recycling Due to Charging in England Net <strong>of</strong> Disposal<br />

(all figures expressed as savings in tonnes CO2 equivalent)<br />

Eunomia, EfW ERM Low, EfW ERM High, EfW WRAP<br />

EfW<br />

Recycling Total 1,050,150 247,590 627,641<br />

Disposal Total 199,117 42,207 356,026<br />

Net Benefit 851,033 205,383 271,615 591,199<br />

Eunomia, Landfill ERM Low, Landfill ERM High, Landfill WRAP<br />

Landfill<br />

Recycling Total 1,050,150 247,590 627,641<br />

Disposal Total -324,745 -181,045 -468,445<br />

Net Benefit 1,374,895 428,635 1,096,086 991,272<br />

Source: Hogg, D., Wilson, D., Gibbs, A., Astley, M., Papineschi, J. (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong><br />

Household Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra.<br />

Consequently, it was estimated that the monetised benefits for England associated<br />

with avoided GHGs alone would be <strong>of</strong> the order:


146<br />

� £7-30 million where the avoided disposal routes are EfW; and<br />

� £15-48 million where the avoided disposal routes are landfill.<br />

In per household terms, therefore, one would expect inclusion <strong>of</strong> these benefits to<br />

increase the overall benefits associated with charging schemes by:<br />

� £0.51-£2.17 per household covered by the charging scheme where the<br />

avoided disposal route is EfW; and<br />

� £1.09 - £3.47 per household covered by the charging scheme where the<br />

avoided disposal route is landfill.<br />

Table 8-8: Monetised GHG-related Benefits from Charging in England, Recycling Only<br />

29/09/09<br />

Eunomia,<br />

Eunomia,<br />

EfW EfW<br />

ERM ERM Low,<br />

Low,<br />

EfW<br />

ERM ERM ERM High,<br />

High,<br />

EfW<br />

WRAP WRAP EfW<br />

EfW<br />

Avoided GHG Related Damages £15,086,496 £3,640,873 £4,814,992 £10,480,340<br />

Eunomia,<br />

Eunomia,<br />

Landfill<br />

Landfill<br />

ERM ERM Low,<br />

Low,<br />

Landfill<br />

Landfill<br />

ERM ERM ERM High,<br />

High,<br />

Landfill<br />

Landfill<br />

WRAP<br />

WRAP<br />

Landfill Landfill<br />

Landfill<br />

Avoided GHG Related Damages £24,373,133 £7,598,522 £19,430,617 £17,572,541<br />

Source: Hogg, D., Wilson, D., Gibbs, A., Astley, M., Papineschi, J. (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong><br />

Household Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra.<br />

It is clear that the potential for significant cost savings exists, and that whilst reducing<br />

costs, charging can also increase recycling performance. This in turn has the potential<br />

to generate significant reductions in greenhouse gases generated through improved<br />

materials management, That being said, the figures reproduced here must be treated<br />

as indicative, and sensitivity analysis undertaken for the Defra charging review shows<br />

how variation in the extent and pace <strong>of</strong> uptake can affect the extent <strong>of</strong> benefits to be<br />

derived at the national level from the implementation <strong>of</strong> household charging.<br />

8.6 Implementation Costs<br />

Some specific details <strong>of</strong> schemes’ costs are provided in the IWM charging review.<br />

Costs <strong>of</strong> implementing schemes depend upon the nature <strong>of</strong> the scheme itself (sackbased,<br />

frequency-based, weight-based, etc.). They also depend upon the nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

scheme already in place. This is particularly true with respect to billing. Key set up<br />

costs include:<br />

� Informing communities<br />

� Equipping containers as necessary;<br />

� Equipping vehicles as necessary;<br />

� Billing s<strong>of</strong>tware;<br />

� Arranging for sale <strong>of</strong> sacks as necessary<br />

� Introducing teams to check up on fly-tipping<br />

� Service lines to deal with start-up queries


In many jurisdictions, where the pre-existing situation is collection <strong>of</strong> revenue through<br />

flat-rate charging, establishing a new billing system – an issue particularly for<br />

frequency and weight-based schemes - can imply a significant part <strong>of</strong> the set-up cost.<br />

In such situations, prior to pay-by-use being introduced, waste related fees would<br />

have been included as part <strong>of</strong> a wider charge on services provided by, or on behalf <strong>of</strong>,<br />

the public sector. Following introduction, dedicated billing for waste related services is<br />

required. Arguably, in Ireland, this is not an ‘additional cost’ since the bill would have<br />

been sent to households by collection companies irrespective <strong>of</strong> whether a PBU<br />

system was in place.<br />

Much <strong>of</strong> the focus <strong>of</strong> the Defra charging report was to assess the costs and benefits<br />

associated with a broad implementation <strong>of</strong> charging schemes across England. Key<br />

figures are shown in Table 8-9.<br />

The summarised financial cost-benefit results from this report are shown in Table<br />

8-10. These highlight the fact that up front costs can be <strong>of</strong>fset by system savings. The<br />

report highlighted how these savings change as the marginal costs <strong>of</strong> avoided<br />

residual waste treatment / disposal change.<br />

Table 8-9: Key Costs for Introduction <strong>of</strong> Charging Schemes<br />

Sack Sack-based Sack Sack based<br />

Bin<br />

Bin<br />

Volume-<br />

Volume<br />

based<br />

based<br />

Frequency Frequency-<br />

Frequency<br />

based<br />

based<br />

Weight-<br />

Weight<br />

based<br />

based<br />

Unit Price Number Number Number Number<br />

CAPITAL CAPITAL ITEMS<br />

ITEMS<br />

Fleet Fleet Fleet management management s<strong>of</strong>tware s<strong>of</strong>tware £5,000 1 1<br />

Scanners Scanners £1,500 2 2<br />

Delive Delivery Delive Delive ry and and Scanning Scanning Scanning <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Bins Bins Bins 65 65 £65,000 1 1<br />

Startup Startup Call Call Centre Centre 25 25 700hrs 700hrs 8400 8400 up<br />

up<br />

to to to 30<br />

30<br />

£30,000 1 1 1 1<br />

Start Start up up Info Info Info £100,000 1 1 1 1<br />

Bin Bin changes changes (averaged (averaged over over 10 10 years) years)<br />

£0.17<br />

Annualised Annualised Annualised Capital Capital Cost Cost per per hhld hhld hhld<br />

£0.49 £0.66 £0.77 £0.77<br />

OPERATI OPERATING OPERATI OPERATING<br />

NG COSTS<br />

Additional Additional Staff Staff for for Implementation Implementation /<br />

/<br />

queries<br />

queries<br />

£24,000 2 2 2 2<br />

Additional Additional Additional Monitoring Monitoring <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Fly Fly-tips Fly tips £50,000 1 1 1 1<br />

Annual Annual Cost Cost per per per hhld hhld<br />

£1.96 £1.96 £1.96 £1.96<br />

TOTAL TOTAL COST COST PER PER HHLD HHLD (before (before billing) billing)<br />

£2.45<br />

1p per sack<br />

£2.62 £2.73 £2.73<br />

Billing Billing Costs Costs (pe (per (pe (pe r hhld)<br />

hhld)<br />

sales<br />

revenue to<br />

vendors<br />

£5.08 £5.60 £5.60<br />

TOTAL TOTAL COST COST PER PER HHLD HHLD (after (after billing)<br />

billing)<br />

Approx<br />

£3.00<br />

£7.70 £8.33 £8.33<br />

Source: Hogg, D., Wilson, D., Gibbs, A., Astley, M., Papineschi, J. (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong><br />

Household Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra.<br />

147<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 8-10: Summarised Cost Benefit <strong>of</strong> the Introduction <strong>of</strong> Charging Schemes in<br />

England<br />

Additional Costs due to rerouting <strong>of</strong> Garden and Bulky <strong>Waste</strong> to CA Sites<br />

Change Change<br />

Change<br />

(£/hhld)<br />

(£/hhld)<br />

£0.38<br />

Introduction Costs £2.82<br />

Billing Costs £4.83<br />

Fly-tip Costs £1.73<br />

Change in Kerbside Collection and Treatment / Disposal Costs -£13.95<br />

Net Costs -£4.19<br />

Source: Hogg, D., Wilson, D., Gibbs, A., Astley, M., Papineschi, J. (2006) Modelling the Impact <strong>of</strong><br />

Household Charging for <strong>Waste</strong> in England, Final Report to Defra.<br />

Annual costs <strong>of</strong> organising and administering billing were modelled at £4.83 per<br />

household. As noted above, it is questionable whether this cost is genuinely<br />

‘additional’ in the Irish context.<br />

It should be noted that these costs were modelling costs (based on researched<br />

itemised costs) for partial (71%) roll out <strong>of</strong> a range <strong>of</strong> different charging schemes<br />

across England. What is not shown in the headline table is the cost benefit <strong>of</strong><br />

universal roll out <strong>of</strong> one or other particular charging approach in any particular local<br />

authority. Sensitivity analysis revealed that the net cost/benefit per charged<br />

household if preferential (the most effective and efficient) charging schemes were<br />

employed may result in an annual saving <strong>of</strong> almost £12 per household. Greenhouse<br />

gas savings are additional to this figure, and as shown in Section 8.5.10 may be in<br />

excess <strong>of</strong> £3 per household depending upon one’s assumptions, and the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

the systems used.<br />

The true delivery <strong>of</strong> these cost savings inherently necessitates a strong and freeflowing<br />

financial relationship between the bodies responsible for waste management<br />

and administration at every level. In practice, policies needs to be carefully<br />

constructed if this is to happen (i.e. to ensure that collection cost savings and avoided<br />

disposal savings contribute to the clean up <strong>of</strong> fly-tips etc.).<br />

8.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> waste prevention, the nature <strong>of</strong> changes tends to be related to purchasing<br />

decisions, and increasing home composting. There is some anecdotal evidence which<br />

suggests that where pay-by-use systems are in place, householders tend demand<br />

reduced packaging. A report for SNIFFER undertook surveys <strong>of</strong> multinational<br />

companies, some <strong>of</strong> whom hinted at possible effects <strong>of</strong> charging on packaging<br />

design: 183<br />

183 Eunomia Research & Consulting and M. E. L. Research for ECOTEC Research & Consulting (2002)<br />

Towards Sustainable <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Practice, Report for SNIFFER, SR(02)05a, April 2002.<br />

148<br />

29/09/09


149<br />

“M&S [Marks & Spencer] sell the same products and packaging across all<br />

stores since they do not think it worth their while changing packaging for a few<br />

continental stores. However, they have experienced clear differences<br />

(‘problems’) in consumer attitudes in Germany and Holland (no significant<br />

differences, relative to the UK, were found in France in this respect). For<br />

example, in these countries, consumers do not like pre-packaged sandwiches<br />

and the use <strong>of</strong> PVC. M&S responded with a PR campaign to inform consumers<br />

<strong>of</strong> their approach and why they believed it to be good. They felt that it did not<br />

lose them significant market share. In German stores, however, plastic bag<br />

consumption is at a far lower level than in the UK, and they also had to<br />

introduce a reusable canvas bag to meet customer demand/pressure.<br />

M&S have found that training German staff has been interesting in that there<br />

were far more environmental questions than there would be from UK staff -<br />

probably reflecting both the interest <strong>of</strong> the staff and the fact that they know<br />

that they will be asked similar questions by the public. […]<br />

For example, in Zurich and Berne, householders have to pay 1.50 Swiss<br />

Francs per refuse bag. According to Nestle in Vevey, there is therefore a<br />

definite economic incentive to them buying as much lightweight flexible<br />

packaging as possible.”<br />

A desire for minimisation <strong>of</strong> (particularly) packaging material can lead to<br />

diversification into different or new materials, as well as the development <strong>of</strong> new<br />

techniques for product packaging (greater resort to refillable packaging).<br />

Perhaps the strongest effect in terms <strong>of</strong> technical innovation occurs due to the <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

observed step changes in materials separated and returned for reprocessing. This<br />

can spur the development <strong>of</strong> new or additional recycling industries.<br />

Furthermore, the technical infrastructure necessary to administer (and bill for)<br />

charging schemes (identification and weighing equipment on vehicles, as well as<br />

centralised accounting systems) means that much better data on waste production is<br />

generated when charging systems are put in place. There has been considerable<br />

innovation over the years with the types <strong>of</strong> systems used, the accuracy <strong>of</strong> the data<br />

generated and the reliability <strong>of</strong> on-vehicle weighing systems. Innovation has occurred<br />

in the nature <strong>of</strong> the chips used on bins (which can be in read only, or read-and-write<br />

form, the latter helping to show / prove to residents that their bins have been<br />

emptied).<br />

This gives further scope to assess trends in waste production and devise new<br />

approaches to further progress the objectives <strong>of</strong> sustainable waste management. In<br />

particular, the information obtained from households through ‘identification schemes’<br />

can improve the efficiency <strong>of</strong> vehicle routing and lead to more efficient collection<br />

logistics. Some advanced schemes now make use <strong>of</strong> infrared detection enabling<br />

crews on collection rounds to choose to empty only those containers which are<br />

relatively full. This can lead to ‘bespoke collection rounds’, in which crews’ rounds are<br />

determined by the number <strong>of</strong> bins exceeding the ‘emptying threshold’.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


8.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

PBU for waste comes with a risk that low income households can be inordinately<br />

penalized. If this is the case then the ‘distribution’ <strong>of</strong> the incentive lacks equality<br />

across the social makeup <strong>of</strong> society.<br />

The available evidence suggests the absence <strong>of</strong> a clear link between household<br />

income and waste arisings. If this were the case then the social consequences would<br />

be much reduced. Instead however, the strongest relationship concerning waste<br />

arisings (perhaps unsurprisingly) is most probably related to household size.<br />

The absence <strong>of</strong> such a link between income status and waste generation suggests<br />

the potential for the impact <strong>of</strong> charging to be regressive. A number <strong>of</strong> means to <strong>of</strong>fset<br />

the regressive nature <strong>of</strong> charging exist. These include:<br />

1) Dealing with any perceived increase in hardship through adjusting existing<br />

instruments <strong>of</strong> redistributive policy;<br />

2) Dealing with any perceived hardship through locally implemented redistributive<br />

policies;<br />

3) Dealing with perceived hardship through the charging system itself. Here, there<br />

are essentially three options:<br />

150<br />

A) Reducing the fixed rate tariff;<br />

B) Reducing the variable rate tariff;<br />

C) Offering a levy-free element to the service (e.g. free emptyings in a frequency<br />

based system).<br />

In practice, 2) and 3) tend to be used more widely, with 3) probably being the most<br />

favoured approach owing to the relative administrative ease with which it can be<br />

implemented. In economic terms, 1) would be considered the most efficient policy.<br />

Other options exist to <strong>of</strong>fer reduced charges to compliant households. A number <strong>of</strong><br />

municipalities in Denmark and Italy charge households a reduced fee for those<br />

engaged in home composting. Some municipalities allow a lower collection frequency<br />

<strong>of</strong> residual waste for households with 2 persons. Municipalities with summer<br />

residences have less frequent collection during part <strong>of</strong> the year. Fees are also<br />

typically lower for households in multi-storey buildings compared to households in<br />

areas <strong>of</strong> lower density housing (single-family-housing, rural, semi-detached, detaching<br />

housing), because collection costs are lower from higher density housing.<br />

From the above, it should be clear that the implications <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use for income<br />

distribution are dependent upon the details <strong>of</strong> the scheme itself, but also, the nature<br />

<strong>of</strong> the scheme it replaces. The net outcome cannot be determined in the absence <strong>of</strong><br />

knowledge <strong>of</strong> these effects. However, it is clear that:<br />

� Where residual waste treatment / disposal costs are high; and<br />

� Where the system has a strong effect on waste prevention; and<br />

� Where the system has a strong effect in improving recycling,<br />

then on average, households are likely to be better <strong>of</strong>f as the overall cost <strong>of</strong> providing<br />

the service shows considerable potential to be lowered, at least where the avoided<br />

29/09/09


cost <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment is high (as is the case in Ireland). This suggests, at<br />

least, the scope for dealing with some <strong>of</strong> the effects through the lower costs involved<br />

in service provision.<br />

8.9 Complementary Policies<br />

As identified in Section 8.6 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes, a high marginal cost <strong>of</strong> residual waste<br />

treatment / disposal is desirable to ensure that the savings associated with avoiding<br />

disposal are significant enough to <strong>of</strong>fset additional costs on collection operations,<br />

and the other associated positive costs resulting from this approach. Indeed, any<br />

‘sustainable’ waste management needs to ensure that the external costs <strong>of</strong><br />

treatment / disposal are reflected in the financial costs. This will tend to make<br />

options other than disposal more competitive in financial terms.<br />

Charging for residual waste (and organics) relies on a convenient and effective<br />

recycling system being in place. Such systems work best where materials are<br />

collected from the kerbside. The costs for this service needs to be paid for, but (so as<br />

to maintain the differential charging structure where residual waste attracts the<br />

highest, but still palatable, charge) the full costs can not be directly charged to<br />

householders at the point <strong>of</strong> generation. Instead, producer responsibility on products<br />

and packaging (see Annex 13.0) can be one <strong>of</strong> the most effective measures to<br />

directly fund recycling collections.<br />

8.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

An important aspect <strong>of</strong> charging policies is that they make the individual responsible<br />

for his/her own waste. This can be the strongest direct incentive for the individual to<br />

improve behaviour in line with environmental objectives. The analysis in Section 8.6<br />

shows that PAYT schemes can reduce overall waste management costs. Together<br />

with the impacts on recycling and waste minimisation, this would suggest a trait <strong>of</strong><br />

economic efficiency associated with well administered regimes.<br />

In Korea, average prices for 20 litre bags have increased as municipalities have<br />

sought to maintain or increase the share <strong>of</strong> total service costs covered by VBWF<br />

revenues. Evidently, if such schemes improve recycling performance and reduce<br />

waste sent for disposal, the revenue base declines even though collection costs may<br />

not. The general increase in the average price for a 20 litre bag in Korea is shown in<br />

Figure 8-8 (different municipalities levy different sack charges).<br />

151<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 8-8: Average Prices for 20 Litre Volume-Based <strong>Waste</strong> Fee Sacks, Korea<br />

152<br />

0.40<br />

0.35<br />

0.30<br />

0.25<br />

0.20<br />

0.15<br />

0.10<br />

0.05<br />

0.00<br />

29/09/09<br />

average watse bag price(20 liters)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004<br />

Source: Korea Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> Bulletin, Update Version <strong>of</strong> Issue 1, Volume 1, January 2006.<br />

8.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

A policy which places a financial impact on waste production can inevitably lead to<br />

illegal behaviour to avoid the charge. Issues such as ‘waste tourism’ and illegal<br />

dumping, and how to limit them / deal with them when they occur need to be<br />

considered.<br />

8.11.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Tourism<br />

One such effect, ‘waste tourism’, can be observed where charging regimes are not<br />

enforced in nearby areas.<br />

Linderh<strong>of</strong> et al report a study by the city <strong>of</strong> Oostzaan, which estimates that about 4–<br />

5% <strong>of</strong> waste is taken to surrounding municipalities (which is approximately 13–17%<br />

<strong>of</strong> the reduction in waste prompted by the introduction <strong>of</strong> the weight-based pricing<br />

system in the area). 184 Dijkgraaf and Gradus, on the other hand, carry out a modelling<br />

exercise to estimate the impact <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use on waste in surrounding communities.<br />

Few <strong>of</strong> the coefficients were found to be <strong>of</strong> significance; however, the largest effect<br />

was reported for weight based systems which suggested a 0.6% increase in the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> collected refuse in neighbouring communities. 185<br />

In the OECD charging review, in the case <strong>of</strong> the Spanish municipality <strong>of</strong> Torrelles de<br />

Llobregat, we estimated that the phenomenon might account for 15% <strong>of</strong> the observed<br />

184 V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, P. Kooreman, M. Allers and D. Wiersma (2001) Weight-based pricing in the collection<br />

<strong>of</strong> household waste: the Oostzaan case, Resource and Energy Economics 23, 359–371.<br />

185 E. Dijkgraaf and R. Gradus (2003) Cost Savings <strong>of</strong> Unit-Based Pricing <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong>, the Case<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Netherlands, Rotterdam: OCFEB.


eduction in waste quantities. The municipality would have been particularly likely to<br />

give rise to this type <strong>of</strong> abuse given a) its small size; and b) the fact that no other<br />

municipality in Catalunya (or Spain) was implementing such charges. Other things<br />

being equal, one would expect problems <strong>of</strong> waste tourism to be greater in such<br />

situations (the opportunity is greater and the benefit is maximised). 186<br />

8.11.2 Illegal Disposal<br />

Issues <strong>of</strong> illegal dumping or backyard burning tend to raise greater concern than<br />

waste tourism. Charging has been shown to increase recycling, move materials into<br />

different collection systems and promote prevention activities. However, such a policy<br />

on residual waste stands the risk <strong>of</strong> leading to illegal disposal. It is certainly not true<br />

that unexplained waste prevention equates with illegal dumping (as some authors,<br />

such as Fullerton and Kinnaman appear to have assumed). 187 The rest <strong>of</strong> the<br />

literature, as assessed in the Defra charging review, varies in the extent to which<br />

illegal dumping is shown to be a problem. There is no clearly defined relationship<br />

between the introduction <strong>of</strong> charging systems and the incidence <strong>of</strong> fly-tipping beyond<br />

the statement that there is a tendency for illegal dumping to increase if the issue is<br />

not addressed, and where the collection scheme does not provide convenient<br />

possibilities for source separation <strong>of</strong> a wide range <strong>of</strong> materials.<br />

The literature, and our experience speaking with waste managers concerning the<br />

issue, would suggest that there is a tendency for fly-tipping to worsen once charging<br />

schemes are introduced. The extent <strong>of</strong> this, and for how long it is sustained, are the<br />

key issues. In terms <strong>of</strong> quantification, one problem is that many authorities do not<br />

monitor the extent <strong>of</strong> fly-tipping before a scheme is introduced, or at least, they do not<br />

do so as intensely as they do after it is introduced. This is partly because most<br />

jurisdictions anticipate illegal dumping as a potential problem and therefore seek to<br />

take actions to enforce the system in its early stages to make clear that action will be<br />

taken against transgressors.<br />

In Korea, Hong showed that dumping was substantial after the adoption <strong>of</strong> unit-based<br />

pricing systems. 188 The OECD charging review, however, concludes that enforcement<br />

and the increased scope <strong>of</strong> collection <strong>of</strong> recyclables (notably, the increasingly<br />

widespread collection <strong>of</strong> kitchen wastes) has meant that the problem is becoming<br />

less problematic over time. No information was obtained for the pre-scheme situation,<br />

but following the scheme’s introduction, there has been a steady decline in incidents,<br />

as shown in Figure 8-9, down to 13% <strong>of</strong> the 1995 level. Control measures include a<br />

system <strong>of</strong> fines which effectively encourages citizens to report people disposing <strong>of</strong><br />

186 D. Hogg (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges. Referred to within the text <strong>of</strong> this<br />

report as ‘the OECD charging review’. ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD.<br />

187 D. Fullerton and T. Kinnaman (1996) Household Responses to Pricing Garbage by The Bag,<br />

American Economic <strong>Review</strong>, 86 (4), September, pp 971-84. For a review suggesting that the authors’<br />

interpretation <strong>of</strong> the evidence is flawed see D. Hogg (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection<br />

Charges, ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD.<br />

188 S. Hong and R. Adams (1999) Household Responses to Price Incentives for Recycling: Some Further<br />

Evidence, Land Economics 75, pp 505-14.<br />

153<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


their waste illegally. Of the 75,631 incidents reported in 2004, more than half<br />

resulted in fines for the perpetrators. Overall the scheme is considered a success by<br />

the authorities.<br />

Figure 8-9: Illegal Dumping Incidents since Introduction <strong>of</strong> Volume-Based <strong>Waste</strong> Fee<br />

in Korea<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> Incidents<br />

154<br />

1,200,000<br />

1,000,000<br />

800,000<br />

600,000<br />

400,000<br />

200,000<br />

29/09/09<br />

0<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004<br />

Year<br />

Source: Korea Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> Bulletin, Update Version <strong>of</strong> Issue 1, Volume 1, January 2006.<br />

Cases <strong>of</strong> Illegal Dumping<br />

Reschovsky and Stone (1994) find no relation between illegal dumping and charging<br />

systems (though they find little <strong>of</strong> any effect in their study), while Van Houtven and<br />

Morris (1999) report that ‘<strong>of</strong>ficials … found little to no evidence <strong>of</strong> more littering or<br />

increased use <strong>of</strong> accessible dumpsters.’ In the Netherlands, Linderh<strong>of</strong> et al. (2001)<br />

state that illegal dumping is virtually non-existent in Oostzaan. According to them, the<br />

monitoring system in Oostzaan, with fines for illegal dumping, appears to be very<br />

effective in terms <strong>of</strong> deterrence.<br />

8.11.3 Mitigating Measures<br />

Our experience when discussing fly-tipping with local, regional and national<br />

authorities is that the problem has the potential to worsen after the implementation<br />

<strong>of</strong> charging systems. The question arises as to how to control any potential increase.<br />

The literature (specifically Appendix 2 <strong>of</strong> the Defra charging review) and discussions<br />

with scheme operators suggest that communities which provide comprehensive and<br />

convenient schemes for separate collection <strong>of</strong> materials for recycling and composting,<br />

who also take a pro-active approach to dealing with illicit behaviour, and where the<br />

marginal rates for avoiding disposal are not set too high, are likely to experience<br />

limited problems.


A useful report on illegal dumping, and fears concerning this, together with an<br />

encouraging assessment <strong>of</strong> mitigating measures is given by Skumatz: 189<br />

155<br />

“A detailed report on illegal dumping and variable rates by SERA examined<br />

several kinds <strong>of</strong> data to identify whether illegal dumping has been found to be<br />

a problem. Surveys showed low actual incidence <strong>of</strong> illegal dumping problems.<br />

From interviews with over 1,000 communities that implemented variable-rate<br />

programs, the report found that less than one-fourth reported actual problems<br />

with variable rates, and all said that the problems were short-term and easily<br />

dealt with through fines and education. A small percent insisted that the<br />

focus on illegal dumping actually helped them get a handle on the problem<br />

and the situation improved. All <strong>of</strong> the communities felt that fears <strong>of</strong> illegal<br />

dumping should not be a deterrent to variable-rate pricing, because a variety<br />

<strong>of</strong> effective enforcement options were available to address the problem.<br />

Follow-up interviews with haulers noted that there was some initial increase in<br />

bags alongside commercial dumpsters, but lockable dumpsters usually solve<br />

this problem. All communities recommended fines and visible enforcement.<br />

The report also found that residential waste was not a large component <strong>of</strong><br />

illegally dumped material. The surveys did not find a significant increase in<br />

illegal dumping associated with variable-rate programs. However, it was<br />

difficult to find communities that tracked dumping before and after<br />

implementing variable-rate programs. The most compelling information<br />

uncovered by the SERA study was an examination <strong>of</strong> the composition <strong>of</strong><br />

illegally dumped waste: over 75 percent to 85 percent <strong>of</strong> it was non-residential<br />

in origin (i.e., commercial waste). The largest components were construction,<br />

demolition, and land-clearing waste (over 25 percent), brush (almost 40<br />

percent), and—the only important component <strong>of</strong> household origin—bulky items<br />

such as mattresses, s<strong>of</strong>as, and appliances (“white goods”). Therefore,<br />

communities recommend implementing a convenient “bulky waste” program<br />

concurrently to increase the success <strong>of</strong> the variable-rate program and<br />

minimize the incentives for illegally dumping these awkward materials.<br />

Prompt cleanup, bulky waste programs, lockable dumpsters, burn bans, fines,<br />

and other strategies will help reduce the incidence <strong>of</strong> illegal dumping as a<br />

result <strong>of</strong> variable-rate programs. If a community is concerned about illegal<br />

dumping, variable-can or hybrid programs—which include some base level <strong>of</strong><br />

service for all customers, may reduce the incentives for illegal dumping. The<br />

SERA report includes a wide variety <strong>of</strong> suggestions to help reduce illegal<br />

dumping concerns.”<br />

There are clearly measures that can be enacted to minimise illegal activity. Locally,<br />

enforcement needs to be coordinated with schemes’ introduction.<br />

In Flanders, the attitude <strong>of</strong> the regional waste management agency, OVAM, appears<br />

to be that some residents (a hard core <strong>of</strong> perhaps as many as 5% or so <strong>of</strong><br />

189 L. Skumatz (2002) Variable-Rate or “Pay As You Throw” <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Answers To<br />

Frequently Asked Questions, Los Angeles: Reason Foundation.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


households) will tend towards fly-tipping irrespective <strong>of</strong> whether there is a charging<br />

system in place, though with potential for the problem to worsen with pay-by-use in<br />

place. The approach is to take early action against those who fly-tip and explain how<br />

the system works. Clearing hot-spots frequently is also seen as important. 190 Some<br />

authorities report that bring sites and recycling centres act as ‘attraction points’ for<br />

fly-tippers. The IWM charging review reports that:<br />

156<br />

� In Nijmegen, charging may have increased the number <strong>of</strong> tips at these<br />

‘attraction points’;<br />

� In Comuni dei Navigli, the fact that bring sites for glass and cans appear to act<br />

as attraction points for illegal dumping was leading the Comuni to consider<br />

switching to kerbside collection for those materials collected at bring sites;<br />

� Landkreis Schweinfurt had, as one <strong>of</strong> its strategies to prevent fly-tipping, the<br />

more frequent clear up <strong>of</strong> fly tips at litter bins and at mini recycling centres.<br />

They believed this would reduce the attraction which already fly-tipped waste<br />

creates to those who are considering <strong>of</strong> fly-tipping.<br />

� In Treviso, around 0.3% <strong>of</strong> all waste is illegally tipped. The key areas are bring<br />

sites, and at the recycling centres operated by the responsible consortium.<br />

� Gent reports a maximum level <strong>of</strong> 0.5% <strong>of</strong> waste being fly-tipped. They suggest<br />

the main problems are at, and around, high rise buildings, and that ‘lowincome<br />

residents and foreigners’ are the most frequent culprits. Interestingly,<br />

they have argued for a change in the way the municipality deals with lowincome<br />

residents arguing that they should not be given a ‘compensation<br />

cheque’ by the municipality, but a number <strong>of</strong> ‘free sacks’, or ‘free emptyings’,<br />

so as to reduce the problem.<br />

A study by Webb et al 2006 191 makes some interesting comments around the issue<br />

<strong>of</strong> civic amenity site provision. The availability <strong>of</strong> these, and <strong>of</strong> other waste disposal<br />

sites, is seen as a key determinant <strong>of</strong> fly-tipping. This – and experience elsewhere –<br />

suggests that (quite apart from the quality <strong>of</strong> kerbside recycling infrastructure) the<br />

following have some bearing upon the extent <strong>of</strong> fly-tipping:<br />

� The density <strong>of</strong> CA site provision;<br />

� The site layout (reducing visit times);<br />

� The range <strong>of</strong> materials collected separately, and free <strong>of</strong> charge, at CA sites for<br />

recycling / composting;<br />

� The charge levels for residual waste at CA sites; and<br />

� The nature, and cost <strong>of</strong>, bulky waste provision.<br />

190 Personal comm., Danny Ville, OVAM.<br />

191 Barry Webb, Ben Marshall, Sarah Czarnomski and Nick Tilley (2006) Fly-tipping: Causes, Incentives<br />

and Solutions, Jill Dando Institute <strong>of</strong> Crime Science, UCL, 31 May 2006.<br />

29/09/09


Generally, the view which prevails is that charging schemes are less likely to lead to<br />

illegal activity where recycling schemes are convenient and broad in the scope <strong>of</strong><br />

materials they cover.<br />

One issue with free market competition in collection is that private sector collectors<br />

are not the ones who have to deal with the consequences <strong>of</strong> poorly designed systems.<br />

If illegal tipping, or backyard burning is prevalent, the costs <strong>of</strong> dealing with this tends<br />

to fall upon public authorities rather than collectors themselves (who may be the<br />

source <strong>of</strong> the problem).<br />

In Poland the situation is extreme. There are a vast number <strong>of</strong> uncontrolled dumpinggrounds<br />

on which municipal waste is left. Although dumping-grounds are removed day<br />

by day in many municipalities (in 2003, 6,109 <strong>of</strong> them were removed), in a very short<br />

time they appear again. At the end <strong>of</strong> 2006, municipal <strong>of</strong>fices counted 2,509<br />

dumping-grounds on their area. Tojo estimates that approximately 10% <strong>of</strong> MSW is<br />

dumped in this way. 192<br />

The Central Statistical Office attributes this situation to the fact that not all<br />

households are served by a waste collection system. 193 The fees charged for<br />

collection (anticipated to be higher than necessary resulting from collection<br />

inefficiencies where competing companies serve the same streets), as well as the<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> a system to enforce the use <strong>of</strong> a collection service, may also have a strong<br />

bearing here.<br />

8.12 Lessons Learned<br />

The international review <strong>of</strong> charging systems teaches some valuable lessons.<br />

Charging tends to work best where:<br />

157<br />

� National policy sets a clear and structured agenda for local waste charging;<br />

� The marginal benefit <strong>of</strong> avoided residual waste treatment / disposal is high;<br />

� Separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowastes and recyclable collections include a wide<br />

range <strong>of</strong> materials, and are convenient (typically kerbside collected) – this<br />

tends to limit the likelihood <strong>of</strong> illegal disposal / contamination <strong>of</strong> separately<br />

collected waste streams;<br />

� Charge levels are set with a flat rate fixed fee supplemented by variable fees<br />

so as a) to ensure problems <strong>of</strong> revenue stability do not arise and b) to ensure<br />

variable rates are not so high they give rise to more compelling incentives to<br />

fly-tip;<br />

192 Naoko Tojo (2006) Evaluation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Policies and <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments: Three Case<br />

Studies, Report written as part <strong>of</strong> 6FP project HOLIWAST: Holistic Assessment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Technologies, <strong>International</strong> Institute for Industrial Environmental Economics at Lund University,<br />

Sweden.<br />

193 Central Statistical Office (2007), Municipal Infrastructure In 2006, accessed 13 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.stat.gov.pl/gus/45_1726_ENG_HTML.htm<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


158<br />

� Charges are placed on residual waste taken to civic amenity sites as well as<br />

the kerbside; and<br />

� Charges are levied – albeit at different rates - on all waste streams, including<br />

recycling – this fully integrated approach best delivers the incentive for waste<br />

prevention.<br />

8.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

A political will, and associated public acceptance, can be a very strong determinant in<br />

passing law to allow charges to be made for waste. Despite significant investigation<br />

into the impact <strong>of</strong> charging for waste in the UK showing the benefits it would bring,<br />

this policy remains a political hot potato.<br />

Minimum standards for a quality, convenient collection service including a wide range<br />

<strong>of</strong> recyclables is desirable in order for charging systems to deliver the best outcomes.<br />

Eunomia described a charging scheme in Fingal, Ireland, where half <strong>of</strong> households<br />

had no kerbside recycling scheme available to them. The scheme led to many<br />

protests concerning the system.<br />

29/09/09


9.0 Pay-by-use – Germany<br />

9.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The local competent authorities in Germany (439 cities and counties) raise disposal<br />

fees from their citizens for the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste. These fees are required to cover the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> collection and disposal. The law on charges lays down the principle <strong>of</strong> costrecovery<br />

– the collection <strong>of</strong> waste fees is not intended to generate a pr<strong>of</strong>it. The levels<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste fees, as well as the design <strong>of</strong> the charging systems themselves, vary<br />

considerably across Germany.<br />

In the waste laws <strong>of</strong> several <strong>of</strong> the 16 states in Germany, it is stated explicitly that<br />

charges for the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste shall constitute incentives for the prevention <strong>of</strong><br />

waste as well for the separation <strong>of</strong> waste for recycling (e.g. Art. 9 para 2 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Law <strong>of</strong> Nord-Rhine-Westphalia). In other states <strong>of</strong> Germany these incentives are not<br />

regulated explicitly (e.g. the <strong>Waste</strong> Law <strong>of</strong> Hesse) but their regulations have to<br />

consider the principle <strong>of</strong> waste avoidance in a similar way.<br />

The calculation <strong>of</strong> waste charges in Germany is based around either <strong>of</strong> the two<br />

following models:<br />

159<br />

� Flat rate charging. Households are charged in accordance with the number <strong>of</strong><br />

persons per household (the flat rate model is applied by the majority <strong>of</strong> the<br />

municipalities in Germany). <strong>Waste</strong> fees are usually divided into an annual fee<br />

and a container fee. The annual fee depends on the number <strong>of</strong> persons in a<br />

household; the container fee depends on the size <strong>of</strong> the container, usually a<br />

wheeled bin.<br />

� Pay-as-you-throw (PAYT) charging. Direct charging according to the quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

the waste disposed (pay-per-volume model is used, for example. in<br />

municipalities in the counties Darmstadt-Dieburg and Gießen in the state<br />

Hesse).<br />

Only the second <strong>of</strong> these approaches can be considered a pay-by-use system.<br />

It is important to note that according to German law, citizens are obliged to dispose <strong>of</strong><br />

their waste using the local waste disposal system. Citizens cannot, therefore, refuse<br />

to have a wheeled bin. This is due to the fact that the fees for the public disposal<br />

service have to be paid by the community.<br />

Countywide uptake <strong>of</strong> charging systems has tended to take several years. Darmstadt-<br />

Dieburg County introduced the first charges in 1996 and achieved full coverage <strong>of</strong><br />

municipalities in 2001. Gießen in the Land Hesse took from 2001 to the end <strong>of</strong> 2005<br />

to introduce the fee system across all municipalities.<br />

9.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

There is no statistical overview about the situation in the 439 cities and counties in<br />

Germany due to differences in application <strong>of</strong> waste management systems, including<br />

the charging systems used. Typically, PAYT systems are more common in counties<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


than in large cities due to the habitant density and the higher share <strong>of</strong> large housing<br />

stocks in the larger towns. However, special waste sluices with a volume based fee<br />

levied for disposal <strong>of</strong> household waste are in practice in several German cities in<br />

certain housing areas. In Erfurt for instance, waste sluices have been installed for<br />

4,730 apartments since January 2008. 194<br />

Starting in 1996 in the county Darmstadt-Dieburg, a waste disposal charge per<br />

volume was introduced and implemented using a barcode-sticker on the wheeled bin.<br />

Countywide application <strong>of</strong> the PAYT scheme in all municipalities was achieved by<br />

2001.<br />

The latest structure <strong>of</strong> the waste disposal charges includes a basic flat fee which<br />

includes 12 bin collections per year, as well as supplementary charges levied for<br />

additional pick ups (maximum 12 per year). These fees are described in Table 9-1.<br />

Table 9-1: <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Charge Structures in Darmstadt-Dieburg County<br />

160<br />

29/09/09<br />

Size Size <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> wheeled wheeled bin bin<br />

Basic Basic fee fee per per year year a Fee Fee Fee for for additional additional pick pick-up pick up<br />

50 litre €96.00 €8.00<br />

60 litre €115.20 €9.60<br />

80 litre €153.60 €12.80<br />

120 litre €230.40 €19.20<br />

240 litre €460.80 €38.40<br />

1,110 litre b €3,162.00<br />

a Including 12 collections b Collection every fortnight<br />

Other household wastes, like the Duales System Deutschland “Gelber Sack” for<br />

packaging waste (see Annexes 13.0 and 14.0) and waste paper are not directly<br />

included in the above mentioned pay-by-use system, but the lower costs associated<br />

with those waste streams are taken into account in the overall-calculation <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

charges. Further information on the structure <strong>of</strong> waste disposal charges in the county<br />

Gießen is given (in German) at www.trend-abfall.de.<br />

Authorities recommend a standard volume residual waste wheeled bin at 15 litres per<br />

person per week. Citizens are advised, however, that high separation can mean a<br />

lower minimum volume <strong>of</strong> 7.5 litres per person per week is possible. This minimum<br />

volume relates to this minimum fee which has to be paid by individual households.<br />

Typically, the fees shown in Table 9-2 are applied for residual waste. Lower fees for<br />

organic waste are shown in Table 9-3.<br />

194 EUWID (2008), German news website, www.euwid-recycling.com


Table 9-2: Charges for Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

161<br />

Size Size <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the the the bin bin Emptying Emptying intervals intervals<br />

Fee<br />

Fee<br />

60 litre<br />

120 litre<br />

240 litre<br />

1.100 litre<br />

once a month<br />

twice a month<br />

once a month<br />

twice a month<br />

once a month<br />

twice a month<br />

once a month<br />

twice a month<br />

Table 9-3: Charges for Organic <strong>Waste</strong> Collection<br />

Size Size <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the the bin bin Emptying Emptying interval interval Fee<br />

Fee<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

€71.40<br />

€147.60<br />

€133.20<br />

€277.20<br />

€262.80<br />

€538.80<br />

€1,212.00<br />

€2,472.00<br />

120 litre twice a month €28.80<br />

240 litre twice a month €57.60<br />

In addition to the residual waste, organic waste and packaging waste (dual system)<br />

collection systems described above, 240l waste paper bins are provided for all private<br />

households free <strong>of</strong> charge. This waste paper bin is emptied monthly.<br />

The county <strong>of</strong> Landkreis Schweinfurt in Bavaria is another case in point. In the late<br />

1980s, the system started changing from a one bin to a three bin system. By 1994,<br />

the doorstep collection <strong>of</strong> residual waste, biowaste and producer responsibility<br />

funded recycling fractions (see Dual System Deutschland, Sections 13.0 and 14.0),<br />

supported by separate collections for glass, cans, and paper and card at bring sites,<br />

was delivering a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 58.6% with households only paying for residual<br />

waste collections on an annually charged volume based fee related to the size <strong>of</strong> bin<br />

chosen (i.e. not a “variable” charge after the household’s beginning <strong>of</strong> year decision).<br />

In 1997, by modification <strong>of</strong> the existing system, the County decided to improve the<br />

incentive for waste reduction to reduce costs through the incorporation <strong>of</strong> an<br />

additional (frequency based) emptying fee and also a weight-based fee. The charging<br />

system was calculated in such a way that on average, householders would pay the<br />

same cost after the system’s introduction as before (with higher waste producers<br />

paying more and others less). It is notable that prior to the system’s introduction, the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> residual waste per inhabitant was already extremely low by international


standards at 120kg/inhabitant, making the system’s objectives all the more<br />

challenging. 195<br />

The Schweinfurt system billing scheme works through an annual invoice (billed in 4<br />

instalments) calculated upon the previous year’s performance by the household. Each<br />

year, an adjustment is made to the preceding year’s bill based upon the performance<br />

<strong>of</strong> the household relative to the beginning <strong>of</strong> year estimate. The three part tariff<br />

comprises:<br />

1. A fixed fee. This was intended to cover the fixed costs <strong>of</strong> the collection<br />

infrastructure, including the bulky waste collection, the collection <strong>of</strong> tyres, fridges,<br />

special wastes etc. The annual cost for this fixed element varies with the size <strong>of</strong><br />

residual waste bin chosen (the fixed fee is only linked to the refuse bin). For a<br />

120l bin, the fee is €8 per month, and for a 240l bin, the fee is €16 per month.<br />

The minimum bin size is 120l. It is felt that smaller bins are unlikely to lead to<br />

optimised collection <strong>of</strong> the different fractions.<br />

2. A fee per emptying <strong>of</strong> any bin. The basis for the ‘emptying charge’ is the amount<br />

saved by not emptying a bin. This was calculated as €0.20 per emptying;<br />

3. A weight-based fee. This is set at €0.25/kg for residual waste and €0.15/kg for<br />

biowaste.<br />

9.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and <strong>Management</strong><br />

In Germany the technical side <strong>of</strong> waste management is carried out by specialist<br />

associations for waste disposal (the joint waste management authority<br />

“Abfallzweckverband”). The establishment <strong>of</strong> such an association or the conversion <strong>of</strong><br />

the structure <strong>of</strong> an existing association is considered to bring economic and logistical<br />

benefits in the management <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

In Germany the local municipalities or counties are responsible, by law, for the<br />

collection and disposal <strong>of</strong> waste (Art. 15 para 1 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling and Disposal<br />

Act, Art. 4 para 1 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Law <strong>of</strong> Hesse, Art. 5 para 1 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Law <strong>of</strong> Nord-<br />

Rhine Westphalia). Therefore the local authorities have the right, and indeed an<br />

obligation, to set up waste charge regulations.<br />

9.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

For general aspects see:<br />

162<br />

� Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen,<br />

SRU) Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2008, July 2008 (See:<br />

http://www.umweltrat.de for further information).<br />

� Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen,<br />

SRU) Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2004, July 2004 Council <strong>of</strong><br />

195 Eunomia (2003) To Charge or Not to Charge? Final report to IWM (EB).<br />

29/09/09


163<br />

Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen, SRU)<br />

Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2002, July 2002.<br />

Specific report for the County Darmstadt-Dieburg:<br />

� DA-Di Werk <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Concept (“Abfallwirtschaftkonzept 2007“),<br />

County Darmstadt-Dieburg, August 2007.<br />

9.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

PAYT systems are observed to stimulate the recycling <strong>of</strong> material fractions <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste if appropriate services are in place. It is not so straightforward,<br />

however, to assess the impact on waste prevention. Figure 9-1 shows the waste<br />

streams for Darmstadt-Dieburg, a county with a sophisticated PAYT system using barcoded<br />

wheeled bins.<br />

Figure 9-1: <strong>Waste</strong> Streams Per Capita and Year in County Darmstadt-Dieburg<br />

kg / capita / year<br />

500<br />

450<br />

400<br />

350<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Year <strong>of</strong> First Implementation<br />

Source: County Darmstadt-Dieburg (2007) DA-Di Werk <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Concept<br />

“Abfallwirtschaftkonzept 2007”, August 2007.<br />

Metal cans (recycled)<br />

Packaging plastics<br />

(recycled: yellow bag)<br />

Glass (recycled)<br />

Paper (recycled)<br />

Kitchen and garden<br />

waste (composting)<br />

WEEE (separated)<br />

Residual waste<br />

(households)<br />

The figure shows the total amount <strong>of</strong> household waste (excluding bulky waste which is<br />

not a target <strong>of</strong> the PAYT system, but including waste from small companies)<br />

increasing from 311 kg/capita in 1990 to 423 kg/capita in 2001 – the first year with<br />

the application <strong>of</strong> the system in all municipalities <strong>of</strong> the county. However, this<br />

increase may have been significantly driven by the enhanced centralised composting<br />

service in the county (increase from 13 kg to 176 kg/capita) which may have resulted<br />

in increased waste arisings (see Sections 8.5 and 33.7.1 <strong>of</strong> the Annexes). Centralised<br />

collections may have reduced home composting (there is a high proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

detached houses in the county).


From 2001 to 2006 the total amount <strong>of</strong> all waste fractions shows zero growth.<br />

Although this data does not directly prove the waste prevention effect, the further<br />

reduction <strong>of</strong> the residual waste (from 95 to 82 kg per capita 196) could be an effect <strong>of</strong><br />

waste prevention. Furthermore, set against the context <strong>of</strong> (a) historical arisings<br />

growth, (b) continued economic growth through the period 2001 to 2006, and (c) a<br />

general trend towards lower numbers or residents per property in Germany (which is<br />

known to increase average waste arisings per capita), a zero growth rate in fact<br />

suggests that residents are adapting to the economic incentive to minimise waste.<br />

With just 82 kg residual waste per capita in 2006 the Darmstadt-Dieburg county was<br />

among the communities with the lowest figures in Germany. The increase in material<br />

separated for recycling and composting is also impressive. Although this does not<br />

prove a waste prevention effect, it suggests that a PAYT-system combined with<br />

convenient separation, collection and recycling services delivers remarkable effects<br />

to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> residual waste. The incentive for citizens to prevent and<br />

recycle waste is delivered through the financial stimulus. 197<br />

The overall reduction <strong>of</strong> residual waste per capita from 230 kg/capita in 1990 to 127<br />

kg/capita in 1995 (last year without the PAYT system in all <strong>of</strong> the communities in the<br />

county) and further to 82 kg/capita in 2006 can be considered to have delivered<br />

significant environmental benefits. Residual waste in the region goes to the local<br />

incinerator. The environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling over incineration are well<br />

established, as such the specific emissions per capita caused by the incineration <strong>of</strong><br />

municipal waste have been reduced significantly. Furthermore the increases in<br />

recycled or composted fractions (glass, metals, kitchen and garden waste etc.) help<br />

conserve primary resources and to reduce linked environmental effects associated<br />

with material extraction and processing (compared with recycling pathways).<br />

The Schweinfurt scheme is worthy <strong>of</strong> detailed analysis as it takes an already well<br />

performing system and interlaces volume, frequency and weight based charges to<br />

achieve further environmental improvement (as associated with waste prevention<br />

and increased recycling). In understanding the effects <strong>of</strong> the scheme, one must<br />

understand the linkages between what has happened to collections at the doorstep,<br />

and what has happened at other collection routes.<br />

Figure 9-2 shows the effect <strong>of</strong> the schemes on the quantities <strong>of</strong> material collected at<br />

the doorstep. The effect is clearly dramatic, with collections falling by more than 40%<br />

<strong>of</strong> the original quantity. Figure 9-3 clearly shows that this is an exceptional result,<br />

even when compared with well-functioning schemes elsewhere in Germany.<br />

196 In 1995, the last year without the PAYT system in all <strong>of</strong> the communities <strong>of</strong> the county the amount<br />

<strong>of</strong> residual waste was 127 kg/capita.<br />

197 A private interview with one citizen <strong>of</strong> the Darmstadt-Dieburg county demonstrates that use <strong>of</strong> the<br />

<strong>of</strong>fered separation, collection and recycling systems, allows a household with four persons to choose<br />

the smallest bin (50l) with just five additional pick-ups in addition to the twelve free pick-ups. This was<br />

suggested to have created savings €56, or a 29% reduction <strong>of</strong> the annual bill compared to the<br />

previous year.<br />

164<br />

29/09/09


Figure 9-2: Quantities <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Collected Through Doorstep Collections<br />

165<br />

Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Collected<br />

(tonnes)<br />

16,000<br />

14,000<br />

12,000<br />

10,000<br />

8,000<br />

6,000<br />

4,000<br />

2,000<br />

Source: Landratsamt Schweinfurt<br />

0<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Year<br />

Figure 9-3: Comparison <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Collected at Doorstep, Landkreis<br />

Schweinfurt and Other Counties in Germany<br />

Residual <strong>Waste</strong> per Inhabitant per Year (kg)<br />

160<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

Source: Landratsamt Schweinfurt<br />

149.2 67.89<br />

123.1<br />

Bayern Unterfranken Lkr. Schweinfurt<br />

It might be expected that this decline in residual waste quantities would be explained<br />

through an increase in source separation. However, the quantity <strong>of</strong> material collected<br />

on the door-to-door biowaste collection also dropped by more than 40%. In absolute<br />

terms, the fall was <strong>of</strong> about 5,500 tonnes.<br />

Part <strong>of</strong> the biowaste fraction has simply moved into a different collection outlet. The<br />

County operates a network <strong>of</strong> 29 locations where citizens can bring material from the


garden for chipping. There was an increase <strong>of</strong> around 2,800 tonnes <strong>of</strong> this material<br />

(estimated on the basis <strong>of</strong> a volume <strong>of</strong> approximately 7,000 m 3 when shredded).<br />

Hence, this does not completely explain the reduction in biowaste collections, which<br />

suggests an increase in home composting. A net reduction <strong>of</strong> around 2,700 tonnes<br />

(23kg per inhabitant) <strong>of</strong> biowaste still remains.<br />

Figure 9-4: Biowaste Collections, Door to Door System, Landkreis Schweinfurt<br />

Biowaste Collected (tonnes)<br />

166<br />

29/09/09<br />

16,000<br />

14,000<br />

12,000<br />

10,000<br />

8,000<br />

6,000<br />

4,000<br />

2,000<br />

0<br />

Source: Landratsamt Schweinfurt<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Figure 9-5: Change in Material Received at Chipping Stations (volume), Landkreis<br />

Schweinfurt<br />

Volume Collected (cu. m)<br />

25,000<br />

20,000<br />

15,000<br />

10,000<br />

5,000<br />

0<br />

Source: Landratsamt Schweinfurt<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Year


The bulky waste collections, Figure 9-6, show the effects <strong>of</strong> the expectations <strong>of</strong> a<br />

change in the system. The amount collected showed a sharp increase just before the<br />

change, and a drop immediately after. This suggests that many households had a<br />

grand ‘clear out’ prior to the scheme’s introduction.<br />

Figure 9-6: Bulky <strong>Waste</strong> Collections, Landkreis Schweinfurt<br />

167<br />

Tonnes Collected<br />

7,000<br />

6,000<br />

5,000<br />

4,000<br />

3,000<br />

2,000<br />

1,000<br />

0<br />

Source: Landratsamt Schweinfurt<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Year<br />

Figure 9-7: Paper Collections Through NGO Activities, Landkreis Schweinfurt<br />

Tonnes Collected<br />

2,000<br />

1,800<br />

1,600<br />

1,400<br />

1,200<br />

1,000<br />

800<br />

600<br />

400<br />

200<br />

0<br />

Source: Landratsamt Schweinfurt<br />

1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Year


The county was operating a network <strong>of</strong> 160 mini-recycling centres (bring sites) at<br />

which, typically, glass (colour separated), cans and plastics, paper and card, and<br />

textiles are collected. Paper collected separately by non-government organisations<br />

and through the bring sites increased by 400 tonnes (see Figure 9-7 and Figure 9-8).<br />

Figure 9-8: Paper Collection Through Bring Schemes<br />

Tonnes Collected<br />

168<br />

29/09/09<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Source: Landratsamt Schweinfurt<br />

Year<br />

The amount <strong>of</strong> DSD (i.e. packaging) waste collected changed very little (see Figure<br />

9-9), initially falling, though this was believed to be due, in part, to ongoing changes in<br />

the nature <strong>of</strong> packaging placed on the market.<br />

Figure 9-9: Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Collected (doorstep system)<br />

Tonnes Packaging Collected<br />

2,500<br />

2,000<br />

1,500<br />

1,000<br />

500<br />

0<br />

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Year


The net effect <strong>of</strong> these changes for Landkreis Schweinfurt is shown in Figure 9-10.<br />

Between 1999 and 2000, total waste collected fell by 28%. However, this includes<br />

the expectations-related effects (in which ‘clean-outs’ occurred prior to scheme<br />

introduction). Taking this into account, the reduction was from 52,000 tonnes or so to<br />

45,000 tonnes, a reduction <strong>of</strong> 13%.<br />

Figure 9-10: Net Effect on <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> System, Landkreis Schweinfurt<br />

Total Tonnes<br />

169<br />

70,000<br />

60,000<br />

50,000<br />

40,000<br />

30,000<br />

20,000<br />

10,000<br />

0<br />

Source: Landratsamt Schweinfurt<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

1999<br />

Year<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

Residual<br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

Separately<br />

Collected<br />

Residual waste fell from a pre-scheme average <strong>of</strong> 165kg to a post-scheme average <strong>of</strong><br />

92kg per inhabitant, a reduction <strong>of</strong> 46%. The pre- and post-scheme average recycling<br />

rates shifted from 64% to 76%. This is truly outstanding performance by any<br />

comparator.<br />

Refuse had fallen to marginally more than 50% <strong>of</strong> what was there previously, but the<br />

organic fraction had also fallen significantly in proportionate terms from 33% to 8% <strong>of</strong><br />

residual waste. This implies a reduction <strong>of</strong> around 29% <strong>of</strong> the original residual waste<br />

fraction due to changes in the way in which the organic fraction was being treated by<br />

households. Of course, such analyses cannot be relied upon to provide a completely<br />

accurate picture <strong>of</strong> the changes in quantitative terms, but they suggest a major<br />

change in how this fraction was treated. A survey <strong>of</strong> households was carried out to<br />

find out the main reason for the change, and it is believed that increased activity in<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> home composting was the principal explanation for the change.<br />

The paper fraction, previously 12% or so <strong>of</strong> residual waste, fell only slightly in<br />

proportionate terms to 11% <strong>of</strong> residual waste. Yet, bearing in mind the reduction in<br />

absolute quantities, the reduction suggests that approximately 6% <strong>of</strong> the reduction in<br />

residual waste was due to changes in householders’ handling <strong>of</strong> the paper and card<br />

fraction.


The above line <strong>of</strong> thinking led the County to believe that it could readily explain<br />

around 35% <strong>of</strong> the drop in residual waste, but that the remaining reduction<br />

demanded closer examination. The County considered the possibilities for legitimate<br />

and illegitimate changes in behaviour which could explain the ‘unexplained’ reduction<br />

in residual waste. As regards legitimate routes, the following were considered:<br />

1. A reduction in the amount <strong>of</strong> inert building / DIY waste generated;<br />

2. A change in the use <strong>of</strong> nappies from disposables to re-usables. Statistics and<br />

compositional analysis suggest a reduction from 9.4kg/average-inhabitant before<br />

the scheme to 7kg/average-inhabitant after implementation; and<br />

3. Consumer choices. Some evidence suggests that consumers are changing<br />

consumption habits to reduce the quantity <strong>of</strong> packaging and / or waste generated.<br />

The illegitimate disposal routes are discussed in Section 9.11.<br />

9.6 Implementation Costs<br />

For the local competent authorities the shift to a pay-per-volume system has a –<br />

sometimes considerable – cost saving effect. For example after changing to the payper-volume<br />

system, the county Gießen has saved costs estimated at €1.3 million per<br />

year. The investment costs required for a district or county to change to this waste<br />

charge system are effectively more than balanced by the reduction in the quantities<br />

<strong>of</strong> residual waste, and constraint on total waste. 198<br />

The levels <strong>of</strong> the fees (and the corresponding cost savings) differ from county to<br />

county. 199 The differences result from varying utilisation <strong>of</strong> waste disposal facility<br />

capacities as well as the population in the local municipal authorities.<br />

In the Schweinfurt scheme, although collections are only <strong>of</strong>fered fortnightly, for<br />

several bin types the set out rate is close to 50% (i.e. for many householders bins are<br />

being set out approximately once a month). Interestingly, the set out rate tends to be<br />

lower for those using smaller bins. For those using larger bins, the materials tend to<br />

be collected approximately once every three weeks. This change in set out rates has<br />

led to reduced staffing levels. The materials are collected on vehicles, and the prescheme<br />

situation, in which vehicles were operated with a driver plus one crew, has<br />

changed such that they now operate as driver only side-loading vehicles.<br />

9.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The policy stimulates sophisticated collection and recycling systems for multi material<br />

waste fractions. This needs to include provision for centralised food waste<br />

composting or anaerobic digestion. Furthermore, new technologies are brought onto<br />

198 See www.uni-giessen.de/ilr/gaeth/projekte/pro_gebuehrensystem/pro_gebuehrensystem.html; the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> the flexible pay per volume system in the county Gießen was scientifically attended by a<br />

university project at the University Gießen.<br />

199 EUWID from 23.08.2005, p. 11.<br />

170<br />

29/09/09


the market such as waste sluices (each household has a signature key to open the<br />

sluice and is charged accordingly). 200<br />

9.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> distributional effects, one-person-households (who may be<br />

disproportionately penalised by the charging structures) can legally reduce their<br />

waste disposal costs in Germany by sharing services with a neighbour. In this<br />

instance, only one household receives the fee-invoice for the shared wheeled bin.<br />

In Schweinfurt, those who suffer from incontinence problems are given a reduction in<br />

the fixed fee (the fixed component is as for 120l but they are given a 240l bin). The<br />

weight-based and emptying fees are the same. Since the typical breakdown in the fee<br />

is that fixed fees account for 60% <strong>of</strong> system costs, the reduction is significant (30% or<br />

so <strong>of</strong> the usual fee).<br />

9.9 Complementary Policies<br />

“Pay as you throw” policies need a framework <strong>of</strong> suitable collection and recycling<br />

services for an overall integrated and successful waste management system. This<br />

may be specified in national or local governance as minimum service standards.<br />

Policies that ensure residual waste is high in cost will help to encourage diversion <strong>of</strong><br />

material up the waste hierarchy.<br />

9.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

“Pay as you throw” systems are economically efficient and link the costs <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

disposal with the progress in waste reduction and resource efficiency. Where<br />

treatment and disposal <strong>of</strong> residual waste is high in cost, charges provide the stimulus<br />

to reduce residual waste, leading to cost (and environmental) savings.<br />

Due to the transparency <strong>of</strong> charging for the individual households, systems are<br />

considered to be fair for the citizens as well as good for the environment. It is quite<br />

typical for responsible politicians <strong>of</strong> engaged communities to discuss success stories<br />

in the local media, thereby re-engaging citizens to actively participate in the system.<br />

Flat rate per-person charging system means there are no incentives to avoid waste,<br />

because charges are calculated based on the number <strong>of</strong> residents rather than the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> disposed waste. With the introduction <strong>of</strong> the pay-per-volume system, waste<br />

avoidance and separation are directly stimulated by financial incentives. The decision<br />

to introduce the pay-per-volume model (‘waste producer pays’) thus follows both, the<br />

cost recovery principle and the goal <strong>of</strong> waste prevention.<br />

200 There may be lessons to be learned for Ireland in implementing such schemes. The message is that<br />

pay-by-use does not need to be confined to detached and semi-detached houses, but can be deployed<br />

at blocks <strong>of</strong> flats. However, it is very difficult to see why any private collection company would invest in<br />

such systems if the investment might subsequently be used by an alternative contractor (owing to the<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> competition in the market).<br />

171<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The fees per household for those using a 120l bin for residual waste and a 120l bin<br />

for biowaste in Schweinfurt have evolved as in Figure 9-11. The costs which have<br />

resulted are not only lower than those which were projected, but they were 15% lower<br />

in 2002 than the costs prior to the scheme’s introduction. These are figures which<br />

are not adjusted for inflation, so the real cost to householders has probably fallen by<br />

approximately 20%. The scheme saves money. It is important to stress that there are<br />

other sources <strong>of</strong> revenue for the scheme. The charges paid by households cover all<br />

system costs.<br />

Figure 9-11: Evolution in Average Costs for Households Using 120l Refuse Bin and<br />

120l Biowaste Bin, Schweinfurt<br />

Cost (£ per household)<br />

172<br />

160<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

1996-1999 (actual) Future cost projected in<br />

2000 (assuming incineration<br />

<strong>of</strong> residual)<br />

2000 (actual) 2001(actual) 2002 (actual)<br />

The scheme costs are shown in Table 9-4. As mentioned previously, there are savings<br />

on logistics as well as disposal. Furthermore, there have been savings on the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

invoicing.<br />

Table 9-4: Annual Costs and Savings Relative to Pre-scheme Situation. Schweinfurt<br />

Costs DM Costs (approx. €/hhld)<br />

System cost (hardware, s<strong>of</strong>tware and containers) DM 750,000 € 8.26<br />

System cost (variable elements) DM 455,000 € 5.01<br />

Admin DM 300,000 € 3.30<br />

Reduction in amount <strong>of</strong> refuse -DM 1,830,000 -€ 20.16<br />

Lower set out -DM 180,000 -€ 1.98<br />

Savings on admin -DM 490,000 -€ 5.40<br />

Reorganising bulky DM 300,000 € 3.31<br />

Fly-tipping (monitoring) DM 142,000 € 1.56<br />

Total Total Costs DM DM 1,947,000 1,947,000<br />

€ 21.42<br />

Total Total Savings Savings DM DM 2,500,000 2,500,000<br />

€ 27.56<br />

Costs Costs Net Net Net <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Savings Savings<br />

- DM DM 553,000 553,000 553,000<br />

-€ 6.10<br />

Year


Prior to the system’s introduction, each <strong>of</strong> 29 Councils were paying DM 500,000 for<br />

each Council to prepare invoicing. Following the scheme’s introduction, three people<br />

were responsible for all the invoicing. This saved DM100,000 on invoicing. In total,<br />

the analysis suggests savings which are less than is suggested by the per household<br />

analysis above. The household analysis in Figure 9-11 above is based on one type <strong>of</strong><br />

system user only, whereas the cost data in Table 9-4 refers to aggregate figures. The<br />

estimated saving was over €6 per household.<br />

An interesting aspect <strong>of</strong> the system has been its effect on incineration costs. Those<br />

operating the system make the point that the operators <strong>of</strong> the incinerator plant clearly<br />

do not want these types <strong>of</strong> system to be implemented as they reduce the quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

waste available for the facility. The incinerator operator is now charging lower rates<br />

for larger quantities. The Schweinfurt waste manager noted that this reflected<br />

completely the opposite philosophy to that which the County wished to follow.<br />

9.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Although illegal dumping <strong>of</strong> household waste occurs, e.g. in public parking lots or<br />

quiet rural locations, these are rather singular and occasional problems which by no<br />

means hinder the overall effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the PAYT policy in Germany. It must be<br />

pointed out that citizens according to German law are obliged to dispose <strong>of</strong> their<br />

waste using the local waste disposal system. Citizens cannot, therefore, refuse to<br />

have waste collected. This is due to the fact that the fees for the public disposal<br />

service have to be paid by the community. This is especially important for Ireland<br />

where there is currently no such obligation for individual households to engage with<br />

collection services.<br />

A principal problem is the contamination <strong>of</strong> recycling bags or bins <strong>of</strong> the Duales<br />

System (for separate collection <strong>of</strong> packaging) by regular household wastes (i.e.<br />

residual waste) especially in urban areas. In this case it is difficult to differentiate<br />

between intentional and unintentional disposal (miss-throw). The costs to deal with<br />

this illegal disposal must be borne by the Duales System and therefore are effectively<br />

funded across all household packaging purchases. Standard practice, however, is<br />

that in case <strong>of</strong> obvious misuse, the recycling bag/bins will not be emptied.<br />

Nevertheless, the proportion <strong>of</strong> waste disposed in this way is small and as such it may<br />

be said that the PAYT is not significantly affected by such attempts at evasion.<br />

The issue <strong>of</strong> contamination has not arisen in the Schweinfurt scheme; biowaste<br />

collections are still above 95% purity and wastage rates from DSD recyclables are no<br />

different from other systems and from the pre-scheme situation. Post implementation<br />

review for the Schweinfurt scheme assessed the following illegitimate disposal routes:<br />

1. Burning <strong>of</strong> waste by households. Regarding this issue, the County sought<br />

information from chimney sweeps. They do not think is an issue, and there is<br />

evidence to suggest that if burning did occur in gardens, that neighbours would<br />

tend to report such activity.<br />

2. It was suggested that some householders might take their waste to their place <strong>of</strong><br />

work. Though they consider this a possibility, they have no evidence to suggest it<br />

173<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


174<br />

is, or is not, an explanatory factor. The County is inclined not to believe that this is<br />

a major issue given the approbation that might follow from peers;<br />

3. Some waste might be flushed into sewers (down toilets), but the County has made<br />

checks with water companies and there is no evidence to suggest a change in the<br />

nature or quantity <strong>of</strong> sewage;<br />

4. Fly-tipping was, <strong>of</strong> course, considered a possibility. There were two critical places<br />

where fly-tipping was deemed likely to occur. One is at the mini recycling centres,<br />

the other is litter bins. There is no evidence <strong>of</strong> increases in disposal <strong>of</strong> waste in<br />

fields and forests and so forth. The evidence that the County gathered through its<br />

monitoring suggests that clearly fly-tipping happens, but the degree to which there<br />

may have been a significant increase is not clear. There has been an increase in<br />

the number <strong>of</strong> cases prosecuted. Penalties for illegal tipping were imposed in 54<br />

cases in 1998/1999, and the number increased to 79 in 2000. The attitude <strong>of</strong><br />

the County is that this is something which happens anyway, it seems that it might<br />

have occurred more frequently in the early days <strong>of</strong> implementation than at<br />

present, and that with the support <strong>of</strong> politicians, the clean up <strong>of</strong> bring sites will<br />

occur more <strong>of</strong>ten so as not to attract others to follow suit. It is not possible to<br />

quantify the quantity <strong>of</strong> material cleaned up. On the one hand, there was no prescheme<br />

data, and on the other, once cleaned up, the waste sometimes enters the<br />

‘formal’ system without data being separately recorded.<br />

The upshot <strong>of</strong> the Schweinfurt evidence is that it is not clear how one should account,<br />

exactly, for around one sixth <strong>of</strong> the reduction in residual waste achieved. However,<br />

the degree to which this is related to undesirable activities is believed to be small,<br />

though clearly not zero.<br />

9.12 Lessons Learned<br />

The levels <strong>of</strong> acceptance and satisfaction among citizens are higher regarding a payper-volume<br />

system compared with the flat rate per-person system. This is due to the<br />

fact that the local competent authorities can pass on the reduction in costs<br />

associated with improved performance in waste prevention and recycling directly to<br />

the citizens. In addition, compliant households observe reductions in their fees,<br />

sometimes considerable ones, directly related to the decreased amount <strong>of</strong> residual<br />

waste for disposal. 201 In the long run the pay-per-volume fee system is more<br />

transparent, since the citizens can control and follow the resulting costs.<br />

From observable data, the effects on waste separation and recycling are <strong>of</strong>ten more<br />

significant compared to waste prevention. However, with PAYT promoting the mindset<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste awareness and the importance <strong>of</strong> separation, this can encourage waste<br />

avoidance (such as home composting) and general waste prevention (such as<br />

smarter shopping).<br />

201 EUWID from 22.3.2005, p. 17.<br />

29/09/09


The case <strong>of</strong> Schweinfurt is truly outstanding. Here, an already high-performing system<br />

was made more so by the application <strong>of</strong> an intelligently designed hybrid pay-by-use<br />

scheme. Weight-based systems, if not designed in this manner (i.e. with a frequencybased<br />

charging element), might lead to high set out rates <strong>of</strong> bins with small quantities<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste. Here, the inclusion <strong>of</strong> both weight- and frequency-based charges acts to<br />

incentivise low set out rates <strong>of</strong> refuse bins. Citizens have clearly responded to this<br />

incentive (so that savings in the quantity <strong>of</strong> residual waste set out for collection<br />

translate into genuine savings in the collection system). The study clearly points the<br />

way towards ‘tailor-made’ incentive schemes to achieve specific objectives.<br />

Generally, waste prevention effects are highest where schemes have previously<br />

collected biowaste free <strong>of</strong> charge, and have then introduced charges for the biowaste<br />

container. A key factor in this ‘prevention’ appears to be increased home composting.<br />

There is clearly a view that weight-based pricing affects waste quantities in the<br />

strongest manner, but there is some concern that such approaches can give a greater<br />

stimulus to illegal behaviour. On the other hand, it is clear that ‘subscription-style’<br />

charging, where households sign up to a particular service option at the<br />

commencement <strong>of</strong> a given period, has least effect as it gives little stimulus, at the<br />

margin, for behavioural change. Consequently, charges per bag, or on the frequency<br />

<strong>of</strong> the pick-up, or on the weight <strong>of</strong> the refuse set out, or a combination <strong>of</strong> the last two,<br />

tend to be the most favoured options. Weight-based systems may <strong>of</strong>fer the promise <strong>of</strong><br />

better performance, but without being coupled to frequency based charges, they may<br />

fail to derive any benefit from improving the efficiency <strong>of</strong> the refuse collection<br />

logistics.<br />

9.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

A basic prerequisite for the introduction <strong>of</strong> waste charges is a legal regulation<br />

requiring local waste charge statutes. Also, households need to be ‘connected’ to the<br />

system – the approach used in German law is a specific obligation for households to<br />

dispose <strong>of</strong> waste through the local waste disposal service. Charging at containerparks<br />

is also necessary to ensure that no evasion <strong>of</strong> charges takes place.<br />

In regard to the technical/logistical aspects <strong>of</strong> operating the pay-per-volume system, it<br />

is important to integrate bar code reader systems (or alternative bin-chip systems)<br />

with collection operations. Additional coordination <strong>of</strong> appropriate collection<br />

frequencies is also important.<br />

175<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


10.0 Pay-by-use – Flanders, Belgium<br />

10.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Flanders is one <strong>of</strong> the few European regions to have set a target for the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

residual waste that should be produced per capita, i.e. 150 kg <strong>of</strong> residual waste per<br />

inhabitant per year. In order to achieve this target, a mixture <strong>of</strong> instruments is used.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the economic instruments used is the PBU scheme.<br />

The PBU system is based on differentiated tariffs (it is known as DIFTAR in Belgium<br />

and the Netherlands): high charges for the residual fraction, lower charges for<br />

packaging and organic waste and no charges for other selectively collected waste<br />

streams (other recycling). This creates an effective financial incentive for households<br />

to prevent waste or to sort out the household waste into different fractions. This gives<br />

Flanders one <strong>of</strong> the highest recycling/composting rates in Europe, i.e. more than 70%<br />

<strong>of</strong> household waste.<br />

The ‘polluter pays principle’ is implemented at three levels through three different<br />

tariff structures:<br />

1) Prevention, at no costs or subsidised: home composting equipment is made<br />

available for a reduced price, free stickers against unsolicited mail for post boxes<br />

are made available, etc.<br />

2) Selective collection, at a partial cost: low charge for waste flows that can be<br />

avoided, such as biowaste (~ home composting) and plastic packaging waste (~<br />

environmentally responsible products)<br />

3) Residual waste, charged at full cost: waste charge covers the costs <strong>of</strong> the disposal<br />

(i.e. incineration in Flanders).<br />

Flat rate charges (in addition to the variable rate element) are also charged to hep<br />

support the cost-recovery for the waste management system.<br />

10.1.1 Prevention<br />

As biowaste used to be the largest fraction <strong>of</strong> the residual waste (30-40%), Flanders<br />

gives a lot <strong>of</strong> attention to the prevention <strong>of</strong> this fraction through home composting. In<br />

most municipalities, composting equipment is available for a reduced price, yearly<br />

education and communication actions are undertaken, a training programme for<br />

‘compost masters’ is <strong>of</strong>fered, composting demonstration areas are set up in recycling<br />

centres and in schools, and similar places. 202<br />

202 For a description <strong>of</strong> the master composting scheme run by OVAM, see, for example, Eunomia<br />

Research & Consulting and M. E. L. Research for ECOTEC Research & Consulting (2002) Towards<br />

Sustainable <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Practice, Report for SNIFFER, SR(02)05a, April 2002.<br />

176<br />

29/09/09


10.1.2 Approaches to Selective Collection<br />

In Flanders, 70% segregation <strong>of</strong> household waste is achieved through door-to-door<br />

collections and bring site methods (recycling centres). Since the municipalities are<br />

responsible for the organisation and financing <strong>of</strong> municipal waste management,<br />

different collection methods (e.g. bags or containers), frequency, types <strong>of</strong> collected<br />

waste and charges are possible. However, the Flemish Public <strong>Waste</strong> Agency, OVAM,<br />

demands minimum fractions to be collected and minimum collection method and<br />

frequency. Where DIFTAR receptacles are mentioned, the price for waste collection is<br />

determined by the weight or the volume <strong>of</strong> containers (specific bags, chipped bins or<br />

other receptacles). Details are presented in Section 10.3 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes.<br />

10.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

A strong driver for the frequent and efficient separate collection <strong>of</strong> many waste<br />

streams is found in the environmental policy agreements or covenants. These<br />

covenants are voluntary agreements between the Flemish government and the<br />

municipalities. The municipalities receive financial support from the Flemish<br />

government when they meet a number <strong>of</strong> environmental management targets during<br />

a certain period. This financial support is partly linked to the performance obtained<br />

and can be considered as a goal-oriented instrument: e.g. in the field <strong>of</strong> waste policy,<br />

financial support is only received when the municipality produces less than the target<br />

150kg residual waste per habitant per year. For certain cities the target is adjusted<br />

taking into account the presence <strong>of</strong> illegal immigrants, tourists, students, etc.<br />

The covenants are financed by the revenues from an environmental policy fund<br />

(MINA-fund), supported by environmental levies on landfill and incineration. The first<br />

voluntary covenant (2002-2004) was drawn up to cover separate collection <strong>of</strong><br />

municipal waste and investment in infrastructure (Milieu als opstap naar duurzame<br />

ontwikkeling, 2001). Nowadays waste prevention is the main priority together with<br />

encouraging the use <strong>of</strong> sustainable materials and products (reflecting past success<br />

with separate collection systems).<br />

10.3 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

Segregation <strong>of</strong> household waste is organised in Flanders as described in Table 10-1.<br />

A differential tariff (DIFTAR) applies to mixed household waste, separate collection <strong>of</strong><br />

vegetable, fruit and garden (VFG) biowaste and <strong>of</strong> waste packaging.<br />

The costs in Flanders for collection and disposal <strong>of</strong> waste are lower than in other<br />

countries with less ambitious targets and lower rates <strong>of</strong> diversion. The overall cost <strong>of</strong><br />

the extended system <strong>of</strong> separate collection based on supply and collection methods<br />

amounts to €220 per year per average family <strong>of</strong> 2.4 people. Of this:<br />

177<br />

� €36 <strong>of</strong> this is paid through producer responsibility price increases (on<br />

packaging, batteries, WEEE, etc.)<br />

� €184 is paid at municipality level. The municipality receives funds from three<br />

sources, each contributing roughly a third <strong>of</strong> the municipality level payment:<br />

� Direct charging for waste – a variable cost based on quantities <strong>of</strong><br />

residual and other chargeable wastes (DIFTAR applies);<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


178<br />

29/09/09<br />

� A fixed residual waste tax per household, covering all fixed costs and<br />

also the variable costs that are not directly charged to the polluter (e.g.<br />

personnel, costs <strong>of</strong> evasive behaviour etc.);<br />

� General tax related to household income.<br />

In 2000, the average price <strong>of</strong> a 60l residual waste refuse bag was €0.66. This has<br />

meanwhile risen to €1.5 on average, and even to €2 in some municipalities. In the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> weight based schemes, some regions have established maximum tariffs with<br />

the objective <strong>of</strong> ensuring that the incentive to dump is not too great. So, for example,<br />

in the Antwerp region, it is considered acceptable to have a tariff no greater than 0.15<br />

euro/kg. 203<br />

Table 10-1: Separately Collected Fractions <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong> in Flanders<br />

Household waste<br />

Fraction Fraction<br />

Collection Collection method<br />

method<br />

Bi-weekly door-to-door collection (more frequent in tourist areas) in<br />

DIFTAR receptacles<br />

Bulky waste CA / bring sites, door-to-door collection, collection on demand<br />

Vegetable, fruit and garden waste Door-to-door collection in DIFTAR receptacles or home composting<br />

Paper and cardboard waste Door-to-door collection and CA sites<br />

Glass waste (glass cullet)<br />

PMD-waste (plastic bottles and flasks,<br />

metal packaging and drink cartons)<br />

Bottle bank – two-colour separations, CA sites, sometimes door-to-door<br />

collection<br />

Door-to-door collection in DIFTAR receptacles<br />

Textile waste CA site, door-to-door collection, separately placed containers<br />

Construction and demolition waste<br />

containing asbestos<br />

CA site<br />

Stone debris – inert CA site<br />

Pruning CA site, sometimes door-to-door collection<br />

Fine garden waste and grass CA site<br />

Metals, discarded iron CA site<br />

Wood waste CA site<br />

Tree trunks Composting facility or CA site<br />

Small hazardous waste (all fractions) +<br />

injection needles<br />

Old and expired medications / drugs Pharmacist<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> electrical and electronic<br />

equipment (WEEE)<br />

CA site (SHW-safe) or door-to-door collection or district collection<br />

(mobile SHW-safe)<br />

CA site and re-use centres, conform to acceptance requirement<br />

Re-usable goods Door-to-door collection on demand, re-use centre<br />

203 Personal communication with Paul Macken, IOK.


10.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> PBU measures is coordinated by OVAM (the Public Flemish<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Agency) through a household waste plan, and realised by the municipal<br />

authorities. A key role is held by the expert centre VLACO, the Flemish organisation for<br />

promoting composting and compost use, as well as home composting.<br />

10.5 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The following evaluation reports are available with specific relevance to Belgium and<br />

the Flanders situation. These have been used to provide the references for this<br />

section:<br />

179<br />

� DIFTAR in Vlaanderen. Evolutie belastingen en retributies 1996-2000, OVAM,<br />

2001, on the evolution <strong>of</strong> differentiated tariffs in taxes and retribution systems<br />

between 1996 and 2000. (Dutch)<br />

� DIFTAR op containerparken, OVAM 2003, manual on how to apply<br />

differentiated tariffs on a civic amenity site for selective waste collection.<br />

(Dutch)<br />

� DIFTAR binnen het Vlaamse afvalbeleid, OVAM 2002, manual for local<br />

government on the implementation <strong>of</strong> DIFTAR systems. (Dutch)<br />

� Eindevaluatie van het afvalvoorkomingsproject DILBEEK, OVAM 1998,<br />

research project evaluating the progressive waste prevention programme in<br />

the municipality <strong>of</strong> Dilbeek near Brussels, using an alternative approach<br />

differing from the common approach in Flanders. (Dutch)<br />

� Evaluatie van de reductie van de terminaal te verwijderen huishoudelijke<br />

afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen in Vlaanderen, OVAM 2002, research report on the reduction <strong>of</strong><br />

the amount <strong>of</strong> household waste that has to be disposed <strong>of</strong> by landfill and<br />

incineration. (Dutch)<br />

� Evaluatierapportage Uitvoeringsplan huishoudelijke afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen 1997 –<br />

2001, OVAM, 2002, evaluation report on the waste management plan 1997-<br />

2001. (Dutch)<br />

� Evaluatierapportage Uitvoeringsplan huishoudelijke afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen 2002-2007<br />

OVAM, 2008, evaluation report on the waste management plan 2002-2007.<br />

(Dutch)<br />

� Het effect van huisvuilbelastingen en retributies op het aanbod van<br />

huishoudelijk afval, OVAM, 1999, on the effect <strong>of</strong> household waste retributions<br />

and taxes on the amount <strong>of</strong> waste collected. (Dutch)<br />

� Gemeentelijke belastingen en retributiesystemen voor de inzameling en<br />

verwerking van huishoudelijk afval - Enquêteresultaten 1996, OVAM, 1996,<br />

result on an inquiry on municipal taxes and retribution systems for the<br />

collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> municipal waste. (Dutch)<br />

� Inventarisatie huisvuilbelasting- en retributiesystemen voor inzameling en<br />

verwerking van huishoudelijke afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen in Vlaanderen - Enquêteresultaten<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


180<br />

29/09/09<br />

1998, OVAM, 1996, result on an inquiry on municipal taxes and retribution<br />

systems for the collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> municipal waste. (Dutch)<br />

� Inventarisatie huisvuilbelasting- en retributiesystemen in Vlaanderen en de<br />

impact op de huisvuilproductie - Enquêteresultaten 2000, OVAM, 2000,<br />

update on municipal taxes and retribution systems for the collection and<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> municipal waste, and its impact on the amount <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

collected. (Dutch)<br />

10.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

In 1991, the national situation was that Flanders produced on average 406kg waste<br />

per habitant per year. 20 per cent <strong>of</strong> this waste (82kg) was recycled or composted. By<br />

2004, waste generation per inhabitant had risen to 560kg a year (this figure stopped<br />

rising in 2002) and 71 per cent <strong>of</strong> this waste (401kg) was recycled or composted.<br />

Residual waste largely goes to incineration with energy recovery.<br />

It is difficult to examine a cause and effect relationship between PBU instruments and<br />

the decrease <strong>of</strong> the generation <strong>of</strong> waste or the increase <strong>of</strong> the percentage recycled <strong>of</strong><br />

composted waste. Household waste policy has always been implemented using a<br />

mixture <strong>of</strong> policy instruments among which PAYT is only one. The evolution <strong>of</strong> the<br />

statistics is influenced also by market shifts (such as the wider availability <strong>of</strong> separate<br />

collection infrastructure, the market value <strong>of</strong> recyclable waste). Even climatic<br />

conditions can influence the figures (warm and moist summers generate more garden<br />

waste). Changes in the way waste data are registered can play a role as well. As a<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> the above mentioned covenants between the local and the regional<br />

governments, company waste that is comparable with household waste is<br />

progressively taken out <strong>of</strong> the statistics.<br />

In any case a correlation can be seen between the progressive introduction <strong>of</strong> PBU<br />

principles and increases in recycling rates. It is reasonable to presume that PBU was<br />

an important factor in supporting this evolution.<br />

10.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The costs <strong>of</strong> implementing DIFTAR systems is fairly well established in Flanders. It<br />

does, however, depend on the specifics <strong>of</strong> the scheme. Different schemes use<br />

expensive sacks, frequency based charging, or weight-based systems. The last <strong>of</strong><br />

these requires greatest up-front investment in vehicles, whilst both frequency and<br />

weight-based schemes may require adjustments to the approach to billing.<br />

OVAM reports a minimal cost <strong>of</strong> €50/family for the implementation <strong>of</strong> a DIFTAR<br />

system (containers, hardware and s<strong>of</strong>tware, adjustment <strong>of</strong> waste collection trucks,<br />

etc.). The cost <strong>of</strong> implementing DIFTAR in a civic amenity site (CAS) averages €80,000<br />

(weighbridge, badges, hardware and s<strong>of</strong>tware, barrier, etc.). 204<br />

204 OVAM (2008) Uitvoeringsplan milieuverantwoord beheer van huishoudelijke afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen,<br />

Mechelen: OVAM.


FOST-Plus reports the following collection costs for separately collected waste<br />

streams: 205<br />

181<br />

� Glass: €1.51/capita;<br />

� Paper-cardboard: €1.01/capita;<br />

� PMD (collection and sorting): €5.61/capita; 206<br />

� Communication: €0.36/capita;<br />

� Other costs: €0.65/capita.<br />

With regard to these waste streams, FOST-Plus pays the intermunicipal organisations<br />

the full cost <strong>of</strong> collection and sorting, in the frame <strong>of</strong> a EPR mechanism for packaging<br />

waste (see Annex 15.0).<br />

10.8 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> DIFTAR systems required some technical changes to waste<br />

collection operations. The first generation <strong>of</strong> DIFTAR systems were sack- or tag-based<br />

(the constraint being on the volume <strong>of</strong> material generated), the charge being levied<br />

through the sale <strong>of</strong> specific sacks, or <strong>of</strong> identifying stickers. These systems remain the<br />

most commonly applied approach.<br />

A desire for more sophisticated systems which better convey the incentive to reduce<br />

the weight <strong>of</strong> waste produced has led to development <strong>of</strong> pay by weight DIFTAR<br />

systems. In this case chipped bins are weighed when loaded onto collection trucks.<br />

Additionally, in the more urban context, underground containers with limited capacity<br />

loading and automated identification systems have been developed (much as with<br />

the German sluice gate systems). 207<br />

DIFTAR may be said to have increased the number <strong>of</strong> segregated waste streams and<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> material recycled. It cannot, however, be seen as the only reason for the<br />

growth and the consolidation in this sector in the last decade (see also Section 10.6).<br />

It may also be noted that municipal waste remains under 10% <strong>of</strong> the total quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

waste generated in Flanders.<br />

10.9 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

DIFTAR could affect social inequality where more wealthy households are able to<br />

afford to produce more mixed waste than households on the edge <strong>of</strong> poverty even<br />

when sorting a large amount <strong>of</strong> their waste.<br />

205 FOST-Plus (2008) Annual Report 2007 (note FOST-Plus is the entity responsible for household<br />

packaging waste recycling in Belgium – see Appendix 15.0).<br />

206 Note PMD = plastic, metals and drinks containers.<br />

207 These systems are dewscribed in the Luxembourg case in D. Hogg (ed.) (2002) Financing and<br />

Incentive Scheme for Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Case Studies, Final Report to DG Environment<br />

the European Commission.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


DIFTAR charges are intended to replace part <strong>of</strong> the municipal taxation on income, as<br />

well as a flat rate municipal waste tax. Low income individuals <strong>of</strong>ten do not pay<br />

income taxes so it is possible that waste associated costs may be increased for this<br />

section <strong>of</strong> society. However, social correction mechanisms have been introduced by<br />

different municipal authorities to reduce disproportionate effects. Specific exclusions<br />

apply for families with newborn children to account for diaper waste (the use <strong>of</strong><br />

reusable diapers is only marginally introduced in Flanders). Low income families and<br />

families with newborn children usually get a number <strong>of</strong> residual waste bags for free,<br />

e.g. 20 to 40 bags per year.<br />

Ideologically, DIFTAR ought to replace an equal income generated from surtaxes or<br />

municipal waste taxes. However, several municipalities have introduced DIFTAR and<br />

only partially reduced municipal taxes, thus leading to a general increase in the<br />

revenue take from households. This diminishes the social acceptance <strong>of</strong> DIFTAR and,<br />

more generally, <strong>of</strong> environmental taxation.<br />

10.10 Complementary Policies<br />

DIFTAR systems should be combined with policy measures that ensure alternative<br />

avenues for individual materials. These alternatives need to be easily accessible for<br />

individuals. Minimal standards for separate collection have been deemed necessary<br />

in Flanders, ensuring that when DIFTAR schemes are introduced, households’<br />

propensity to resort to fly tipping is minimised. <strong>Waste</strong> minimisation (and ease <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling) policy measures need also to be targeted at producers and distributors.<br />

DIFTAR ought also to be combined with initiatives to enhance the home treatment <strong>of</strong><br />

biowaste. One way <strong>of</strong> doing this, which is used in many Flemish authorities, is the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> charging for the biowaste container. Home treatment can be realised<br />

by promoting home composting or ‘chicken projects’. Several municipalities in<br />

Flanders actively promote the ownership <strong>of</strong> chickens because they eat leftover<br />

biowaste. An average consumption <strong>of</strong> 150g/day kitchen waste or 50 kg/year can be<br />

reached. The Animal By-Product Regulation needs to be observed when feeding<br />

chickens with kitchen waste. The material is not considered to be waste, as it is not<br />

discarded, and it is in principle fit for human consumption. However, three important<br />

principles needs to be respected:<br />

182<br />

� The food chain has to be controlled through to the end consumer;<br />

� Cannibalism must be avoided; and<br />

� Feeding with animal products is forbidden.<br />

The effects on the private chicken owner are that no meat, fish or meat products may<br />

be given to the chicken, and no kitchen waste with meat (like spaghetti sauce). The<br />

eggs and the meat <strong>of</strong> the chicken are only destined for private consumption.<br />

Policies that make residual waste more expensive help to encourage diversion <strong>of</strong><br />

material up the waste hierarchy.<br />

10.11 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

In principle, waste charging policies ought to be financially neutral for the government<br />

or municipality, as long as PBU systems replace existing flat fee taxation. The aim is<br />

29/09/09


to recover costs in such a way that an incentive is given to households to segregate<br />

waste, and reduce waste generation.<br />

While the flat taxation system has no link to (or impact on) the quantities <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

generated by individual citizens, the DIFTAR financing system does discriminate<br />

between small and large waste producers. The consequence is that individuals are<br />

directly incentivised to improve their waste production behaviour. The resultant<br />

reduction in residual waste can translate into a reduction in net costs.<br />

It may be said, therefore, that such a regulatory system ensures a better<br />

correspondence between financial costs (charges for waste production placed on<br />

individuals) and environmental costs (associated with waste disposal) and it may<br />

therefore be considered a move towards a more economically efficient pricing system<br />

which shifts society towards a more optimal allocation <strong>of</strong> resources. It might not be<br />

‘efficient’ in the strict sense, but it is likely to be more efficient than a policy where no<br />

variable charge element exists, and where ‘over-use’ <strong>of</strong> waste services results from a<br />

zero marginal cost regime.<br />

10.12 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

With the introduction <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use schemes such as pay-by-use there is always<br />

concern that an increase in evasive behaviour might occur, such as illegal dumping,<br />

waste tourism, backyard incineration, and contamination <strong>of</strong> separated waste<br />

fractions. There is currently no information in the available literature as to whether<br />

this has been the case in Flanders. Some municipalities report there has been an<br />

increase in illegal dumping, while others (mainly the intermunicipal organisations who<br />

have insight into the total amounts <strong>of</strong> waste across municipalities) contradict this.<br />

The argument on illegal dumping and waste tourism has been used very frequently in<br />

the discussion by the people opposed to PBU, but an increase in dumping or waste<br />

tourism was not substantiated through scientific studies. This may not exclude<br />

occasional cases <strong>of</strong> illegal avoidance in response to PBU systems.<br />

The quality <strong>of</strong> segregated waste appears currently to be high, and targets are aimed<br />

to further reduce contamination. The current targets are a maximum <strong>of</strong> 3%<br />

contamination for VFG (vegetable, fruit and garden waste) and paper and cardboard<br />

waste, 5% for wood and glass waste, 15% for construction and demolition waste, and<br />

5 to 15% for textile waste.<br />

10.13 Lessons Learned<br />

The Flanders experience may be summarised as follows:<br />

183<br />

� PBU systems are accepted when they are not perceived by the population as<br />

an additional cost, but as a benefit for those producing less waste.<br />

Communication and a clear and obvious link with flat rate tax cuts is<br />

necessary.<br />

� PBU can only be successful if an infrastructure for separate collection is<br />

available to allow producers to avoid using the residual waste collection<br />

service. Since PBU can result in high captures <strong>of</strong> recyclables, it can create the<br />

environment for cost-effective collection <strong>of</strong> additional selective material<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


184<br />

29/09/09<br />

streams. Charging at containerparks is important to maintain the incentive to<br />

recycle (and not allow a free outlet for waste);<br />

� The concept that PBU can enhance fly-tipping or illegal waste activity has to be<br />

regarded on its own merits as no scientific studies in Flanders have proved the<br />

existence <strong>of</strong> a relation between the two. It should be noted, however, that<br />

typically, the variable charge element in Flanders is <strong>of</strong> the order €60 per<br />

household per annum. The payment <strong>of</strong> such a charge does not constitute a<br />

major incentive to dump waste (indeed, it might cost more to drive to a<br />

relevant place and dump the waste);<br />

� PBU requests mitigating measures for people at the edge <strong>of</strong> poverty and for<br />

families with very young children.<br />

10.14 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> PBU systems needs to be coupled with a reduction in<br />

alternative forms <strong>of</strong> taxation. As such, a working relationship needs to be in place<br />

between the body administering waste charges (potentially the local authority via<br />

waste collection companies) and the bodies responsible for other financing<br />

mechanisms (both local and central government).<br />

Social acceptance <strong>of</strong> PBU systems is best achieved where there is a high level <strong>of</strong><br />

public awareness <strong>of</strong> the environmental issues concerning waste. Public education<br />

programmes may help create the public will to take responsibility for its own waste.<br />

Although industry will quickly adapt to PBU (since new market opportunities for waste<br />

collection, recovery and treatment will be created), a basic infrastructure with<br />

sufficient recycling capacity remains necessary.


11.0 Landfill Levy - Ireland<br />

11.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Ireland has a number <strong>of</strong> targets to meet in relation to waste management. A target <strong>of</strong><br />

diverting 50% <strong>of</strong> household waste from landfill by 2013 remains some distance away,<br />

with only about 26% recovered in Ireland in 2007, though this has increased from<br />

22% in 2006.<br />

The relatively low cost <strong>of</strong> landfill in Ireland had contributed to an over-reliance on this<br />

waste management option and mitigated against other, more desirable, waste<br />

recovery options. One instrument used to combat this was the introduction <strong>of</strong> a<br />

landfill levy.<br />

The Government introduced a levy <strong>of</strong> €15 per tonne on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste on the 1st<br />

<strong>of</strong> June 2002 under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) Regulations 2002. On the<br />

1st <strong>of</strong> July 2008, the landfill levy rate was increased to €20 per tonne for each tonne<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong> at authorised landfill facilities.<br />

There are proposals in place to amend the levy, which would include significant<br />

immediate increase to the landfill levy, with the upper limits <strong>of</strong> the levy also to be<br />

significantly increased. Furthermore, it is known that the Government is considering<br />

broadening the landfill levy such that it becomes a waste facility levy, encompassing<br />

incineration (see also Annex 56.2.1).<br />

11.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The landfill levy was introduced to encourage the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill<br />

and generate revenues that can be applied in support <strong>of</strong> waste minimisation and<br />

recycling initiatives.<br />

The landfill levy emerged, and has evolved in the following ways:<br />

� 1998 1998 - Changing Our Ways emphasised the need for producers <strong>of</strong> waste to bear<br />

the full costs <strong>of</strong> waste collection, treatment and disposal, in accordance with the<br />

Polluter Pays Principle and advocates that the level <strong>of</strong> waste charges imposed<br />

should vary according to usage, so as to incentivise waste minimisation and<br />

recovery. In response to this the Government decided to introduce a landfill levy<br />

in 2002, to encourage the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill.<br />

� 2002 2002 – A levy <strong>of</strong> €15 per tonne on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste was introduced on 1<br />

June 2002 under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) Regulations 2002. The<br />

levy was designed to encourage the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill and<br />

generate revenues that can be applied in support <strong>of</strong> waste minimisation and<br />

recycling initiatives. All levies are remitted to the Environment Fund. There are<br />

exemptions under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) Regulations, 2002,<br />

including the following summarised materials:<br />

185<br />

• non-hazardous inert waste from construction and demolition activity used<br />

for landfill site engineering;<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


186<br />

29/09/09<br />

• excavation spoil used for landfill site engineering;<br />

• stabilised waste arising from the composting <strong>of</strong> the biodegradable<br />

fraction <strong>of</strong> municipal waste (to which fraction sewage sludge may have<br />

been added);<br />

• waste arising from street cleaning activities;<br />

• illegally deposited waste;<br />

• residues from filtration during the extrusion <strong>of</strong> recycled polymeric<br />

material:<br />

• non-metallic residues from the shredding <strong>of</strong> end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles, white<br />

goods and other metal waste; and<br />

• dredge spoil from inland waterways and harbours.<br />

� 2006 2006 - As a penalty for those who illegally deposit waste, the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) (Amendment) Regulations 2006 introduced a levy <strong>of</strong><br />

€20 per tonne for each tonne <strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong> at unauthorised facilities on<br />

and from 28 July 2006. This means that persons responsible for the illegal<br />

deposition must pay the levy and remove the waste, as required by Section 60<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> Direction, and remediate the land, apart from any other penalties that<br />

may be imposed through the courts;<br />

� 2008 2008 - As <strong>of</strong> 1 July 2008, the Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local<br />

Government increased the landfill levy, using the power available to him under<br />

the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Acts. The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) Order<br />

2008 amends section 73(3) <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Acts 1996 to 2008 to<br />

allow for the landfill levy to be increased from €15 per tonne to €20 per tonne<br />

for each tonne <strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong> at an authorised landfill facility;<br />

� 2008 2008 (August) (August) – The Government initiated a Regulatory Impact Assessment<br />

(RIA) for a <strong>Waste</strong> Facility Levy (WFL) which would include a significant immediate<br />

increase to the landfill levy, with the upper limits <strong>of</strong> the levy also to be<br />

significantly increased. Furthermore, the landfill levy is to be broadened to a<br />

waste facility levy. The RIA for the <strong>Waste</strong> Facility Levy (WFL) was forwarded to<br />

interested parties on the 29th <strong>of</strong> August for comment. The results <strong>of</strong> the RIA are<br />

not currently publicly available.<br />

11.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The policy development chronology is detailed in the Section above.<br />

11.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The key organisations involved in implementation are:<br />

� The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage and Local Government;<br />

� The Local Authorities;<br />

� The Controller and Auditor General; and


187<br />

� Landfill operators.<br />

Local Authorities effectively act as collectors <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy. To the extent that they<br />

operate landfills themselves, they are required to remit their levy liability directly to<br />

the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage and Local Government (DoEHLG). Operators<br />

<strong>of</strong> private landfill facilities are required to remit their levy liability to the relevant local<br />

authority in whose functional area the facility is located. The authority will then<br />

transfer the revenue to the DoEHLG.<br />

The DoEHLG publishes an Environment Funds Account Report. This report details the<br />

income from the environmental levy on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste and also from the<br />

environmental levy on plastic bags.<br />

11.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

The income from the landfill levy is a direct measure <strong>of</strong> the waste being disposed <strong>of</strong> in<br />

a landfill. This allows the DoEHLG to examine if this levy actually disincentives waste<br />

contractors (public and private) from disposing <strong>of</strong> waste in landfills.<br />

It is the function <strong>of</strong> each local authority to enforce and audit compliance with the levy<br />

requirement within its functional area. The local authorities must prepare and submit<br />

annual reports to the Minister <strong>of</strong> the Environment and Local Government on their<br />

enforcement activities. Section 12 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy)<br />

Regulations 2008 states that:<br />

“For the purpose <strong>of</strong> ensuring compliance with these Regulations, a relevant<br />

landfill facility shall be subject to inspection and audit by, as the case may be,<br />

a relevant local authority, a Local Government Auditor or any other auditor<br />

appointed by the Minister or a local authority for that purpose.”<br />

11.5.1 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The effect on waste prevention <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy is somewhat indirect and therefore<br />

very difficult to measure. Even if one could identify a change in the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

generated, tracing back this to the levy itself would not be straightforward. There are<br />

no evaluation studies, which have really sought to understand the effects <strong>of</strong> the levy<br />

other than in respect <strong>of</strong> the revenue generated.<br />

During the course <strong>of</strong> this review, work has been published concerning the way in<br />

which PBU systems might interface with the landfill levy to influence waste arisings,<br />

and to influence the level <strong>of</strong> recycling achievement. However, these studies assume a<br />

direct correspondence between PBU systems and the level <strong>of</strong> the levy, suggesting<br />

that weight based systems necessarily reflect the cost <strong>of</strong> disposal directly in their<br />

existing, and future, pricing structures. Whilst this could be the case, and whilst some<br />

schemes such as the Schweinfurt scheme described in Annex 9.0, seek to relate<br />

weight-based pricing directly to the marginal benefits <strong>of</strong> avoided disposal, it is not<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


necessarily clear that systems do price on the basis <strong>of</strong> landfill disposal costs, nor that<br />

they would necessarily do so in the future. 208<br />

The Environmental Fund allows one to review the revenue from this levy, which can<br />

be used as part <strong>of</strong> the picture needed to assess its effectiveness. An audit <strong>of</strong> the<br />

financial statements <strong>of</strong> the Environment Fund for the year ended the 31st December<br />

2007 under Section 74 (6) <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act 1996 (as amended) was<br />

carried out by the DoEHLG. Table 11-1 represents the amounts collected by the local<br />

authorities in respect <strong>of</strong> the Environmental Levy on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste from 2002 to<br />

2007.<br />

Table 11-1: Landfill Levy Funds 2002 - 2007<br />

Environmental<br />

Levy on the<br />

Landfill <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

188<br />

29/09/09<br />

2002 2002 2003 003 003 2004 2004 2005 2005 2006 2006 2007<br />

2007<br />

€17,868,726 €29,359,585 €26,765,514 €27,798,605 €30,750,433 €33,398,929<br />

Source: <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage & Local Government, 2002 – 2007<br />

It is apparent from the table above that the revenue earned from the landfill levy<br />

increased between 2005 and 2006.<br />

Various attempts to analyse the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the landfill tax have concluded that it<br />

has affected construction and demolition wastes (C&D), and commercial and<br />

industrial (C&I) wastes, but that its affect on household waste has been limited thus<br />

far. The National <strong>Waste</strong> Database Report 2006 indicates that household waste<br />

generation increased in 2006 by 229,774 tonnes when compared with 2005 figures,<br />

as shown in Table 3-2. This table also illustrates that the amount <strong>of</strong> waste generated<br />

since 2001 has increased by 33%.<br />

208 One report highlights a mean across all areas <strong>of</strong> €0.0442/kg with a maximum <strong>of</strong> 0.460/kg and a<br />

standard deviation <strong>of</strong> €0.104/kg (J. Curtis, S. Lyons & A. O’Callaghan-Platt (2009) Managing<br />

Household <strong>Waste</strong> in Ireland: Behavioural Parameters and <strong>Policy</strong> Options, ESRI Working Paper 295,<br />

http://www.esri.ie/UserFiles/publications/20090728095754/WP295.pdf . However, this report<br />

included areas without weight-based charging, so the average figure would be biased downwards by<br />

zero values in some areas. The high end figure suggests that the pricing in weight based systems might<br />

not always be closely related to landfill gate fees, though clearly, there may be some influence from the<br />

gate fee through to the marginal charge rate. At the high end <strong>of</strong> this range, however – equivalent to a<br />

€460 per tonne disposal cost – changes occasioned by changes in landfill gate fee might have a<br />

proportionately lower additional effect than in cases where the marginal weight-based charge is<br />

currently lower.


Table 11-2: Trends in Household <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Quantity<br />

Landfilled<br />

Quantity<br />

Recovered<br />

189<br />

2001 2001 2002 2002 2003 2003 2004 2004 2005 2005 2006 2006 2006 2007<br />

2007<br />

1,254,857 1,294,061 1,231,109 1,214,908 1,198,504 1,379,246 1,200,980<br />

74,887 132,602 185,753 285,872 344,964 393,995 424,510<br />

Total Total 1,329,744 1,426,662 1,426,662 1,416,862 1,416,862 1,500,780 1,500,780 1,543,468 1,543,468 1,773,242 1,773,242 1,773,242 1,625,490<br />

1,625,490<br />

Source: National <strong>Waste</strong> Database Reports, 2006 and 2007<br />

When the levy was first introduced in Ireland, landfill gate fees were on a rising trend,<br />

therefore (it has been suggested that) there was no real requirement to increase the<br />

levy while landfill gate fees were on an upwards trend. In recent years however, gate<br />

fees in Ireland have started to decrease.<br />

� The average landfill gate fee in Ireland in 1999 was €30; 209.<br />

� The average landfill gate fee in Ireland in 2002 was €102 (excluding landfill tax);<br />

� In 2005 the average landfill gate fee was €124.50 (excluding landfill tax). 210<br />

There are local variations for example the average gate fee in the Cork Region<br />

was €182.50 in 2005 (excluding landfill tax);<br />

� In 2006 the average landfill gate fee was €120.00 (excluding landfill tax); 211<br />

� The average landfill gate fee in Ireland in 2007 was €112 per tonne (excluding<br />

landfill tax), therefore it seems that the general trend in landfill gate fees are<br />

returning to the 2002 levels. 212 In some parts <strong>of</strong> Ireland, gate fees excluding tax<br />

have fallen to €80 per tonne.<br />

Landfill gate fees can vary considerably across the country due to a number <strong>of</strong> factors<br />

such as the amount <strong>of</strong> excess landfill capacity available, the amount <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

generated and the availability <strong>of</strong> alternative landfills and waste treatment options in<br />

the region.<br />

Although Ireland has some <strong>of</strong> the highest landfill gate fees (pre-levy) <strong>of</strong> any Member<br />

State, it has one <strong>of</strong> the lowest levies. However, it has to be highlighted that many<br />

countries with high landfill taxes in place also have in place landfill bans or<br />

209 Forfás Research, http://www.smallbusinessforum.ie<br />

210 Study Completed by TOBIN Consulting Engineers in December 2006<br />

211 Forfás (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in Ireland, Benchmark Analysis and <strong>Policy</strong> Requirements, March<br />

2007.<br />

212 Forfás (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in Ireland, Benchmark Analysis and <strong>Policy</strong> Requirements, May<br />

2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


estrictions (see Annexes 52.0 to 55.0), so that the option <strong>of</strong> landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

without any form <strong>of</strong> treatment is progressively outlawed completely. The effectiveness<br />

<strong>of</strong> the levy is, to some degree, being undermined by the reduction in the cost <strong>of</strong> the<br />

gate fee per tonne. This is even more significant when considered in real terms.<br />

Whilst gate fees appear to be declining in nominal terms in recent years, between<br />

2002 and 2008, the levy’s effectiveness was simply being eroded by inflation. Table<br />

11-3 details the landfill gate fee inclusive <strong>of</strong> the levy, and the proportion accounted<br />

for by the levy. It is apparent that the landfill levy <strong>of</strong> €15 per tonne as a percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

the landfill gate fee remained similar over this six year period. The fact that the levy<br />

has remained constant in nominal terms has meant that as pre-levy gate fees fall, so<br />

the total costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling are also declining, not just in nominal terms, but in real<br />

terms as well.<br />

Table 11-3: Percentage <strong>of</strong> Landfill Levy on Gate Fee<br />

Date Gate Fee (incl levy) Landfill Levy as % Total Gate Fee<br />

2002 €117.00 12.8%<br />

2005 €139.50 10.8%<br />

2006 €135.00 11.1%<br />

2007 €127.00 11.8%<br />

* Inclusive <strong>of</strong> €15 Landfill Levy<br />

The landfill levy was increased in July 2008 to further discourage the use <strong>of</strong> landfill as<br />

a treatment option. The aim <strong>of</strong> the increase was to reduce the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste being<br />

disposed <strong>of</strong> in landfill and to increase recovery and recycling rates (DoEHLG). This<br />

increase in the levy <strong>of</strong> €5 per tonne may not be effective in reducing the rate <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

being treated at landfill as the increase appears only to counter some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

reductions in landfill gate fees that have been occurring in recent years.<br />

Given the above, then it seems likely that the effect <strong>of</strong> the levy will have been<br />

somewhat limited. To the extent that the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling might have influenced<br />

behaviour, probably, the strongest influence will have been exerted in the period<br />

during which landfill gate fees rose in response to tighter regulatory controls.<br />

While the landfill tax is stated on invoices, for businesses that produce little waste,<br />

the landfill tax is minimal. For an <strong>of</strong>fice the average cost related to the landfill levy is<br />

<strong>of</strong> the order €2-3 per month. This gives very little incentive to change behaviour.<br />

11.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

The degree to which environmental benefits will have been delivered by the incentive<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> the levy is not clear. In this context, it is worth examining, for example, the<br />

likely incentive effects to recycle packaging coming from:<br />

190<br />

• Changes in landfill gate fees;<br />

29/09/09


191<br />

• The effects <strong>of</strong> the Repak Payment System (RPS); 213 and<br />

• The landfill levy. 214<br />

Towards the end <strong>of</strong> 2000, a review <strong>of</strong> gate fees conducted by Kirk McClure Morton in<br />

the context <strong>of</strong> work establishing the basis for the landfill levy suggested that gate<br />

fees, in 1999, ranged from IR £15 (€19) per tonne to IR £32 (€41) per tonne for<br />

household and commercial and industrial waste, with one landfill charging a higher<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> IR £52 (€66) per tonne. By 2002, these had reached €102 per tonne, and by<br />

2005, €124.50 per tonne (pre landfill levy gate fees). In short, between 1999 and<br />

2005, the average costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling increased by a factor <strong>of</strong> 5 in nominal terms, or a<br />

factor <strong>of</strong> approximately 3.7 in real terms.<br />

In real 2005 terms, the differential was around €91 per tonne. Relative to the levy, at<br />

a maximum <strong>of</strong> €15 per tonne in these years, this is a huge change. Equally, for waste<br />

producers / collectors, because recycling ‘runs <strong>of</strong>f’ the avoided costs <strong>of</strong> disposal, this<br />

change will have had a significant impact.<br />

It would seem reasonable to suppose that for commercial waste in particular, with the<br />

relatively small (compared with those for household waste) levels <strong>of</strong> price support<br />

through the RPS supports outlined in Table 11-4 below, that the significant rise in<br />

landfill gate fees, as well as the (until recently) upward trend in materials prices would<br />

have been far more influential in increasing packaging waste recycling than the RPS<br />

rates themselves. These rates are only <strong>of</strong> any significance for steel and plastic.<br />

The rates for household waste are more likely to have been influential in determining<br />

the effort made to collect and recycle packaging waste (see Table 11-5). Yet the<br />

quantities <strong>of</strong> packaging recovered through the household stream are far lower than<br />

from the non-household stream (<strong>of</strong> the order a third <strong>of</strong> the recovered material.<br />

Table 11-4: RPS Rates for Commercial ‘Back Door’ <strong>Waste</strong> Recycled (2008 rates, € per<br />

tonne recycled)<br />

Material Material Open Open Loop Loop Closed Closed Loop Loop Recovery Recovery Metal Metal Protocol<br />

Protocol<br />

Glass 4.20 12.60<br />

Paper/Cardboard 4.20 9.45 4.20<br />

Wood 6.30 10.50 4.20<br />

Aluminium 10.50 12.50<br />

Steel 36.75 36.75 10.50<br />

Plastic 52.50 52.50<br />

Source: Repak<br />

213 See Appendix 12.0 for further information on the RPS.<br />

214 One could argue that the Environmental Fund should also be considered as a separate influence.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 11-5: RPS Rates for Household <strong>Waste</strong> Recycled (2008 rates, € per tonne<br />

recycled)<br />

Material Material Material<br />

Kerbside Kerbside Kerbside Bring Bring<br />

Bring<br />

Glass Packaging (e.g. bottles, jars, etc.) 20.00 20.00<br />

Glass Packaging open loop recycling 4.20 4.20<br />

Paper Packaging (e.g. cereal boxes, etc.) 76.23 68.14<br />

Used Beverage Containers 76.23 68.14<br />

Aluminium Packaging (e.g. drinks cans, etc.) 76.23 68.14<br />

Steel Packaging (e.g. food packaging, etc.) 96.80 86.53<br />

Plastic Packaging - Plastic Rigid Bottles 220.00 220.00<br />

Other Plastic Packaging – tubs, pots, trays, jars 76.23 68.14<br />

Source: Repak<br />

In summary, as regards recycling, it seems reasonable to suggest that one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

most powerful influences will have been exerted by the increase in pre-levy landfill<br />

gate fees since the second half <strong>of</strong> the 1990s. Also important in recent years will have<br />

been the buoyant market for secondary materials. Importantly, the market has now<br />

shifted from one where quality barely mattered, to one where the market only wants<br />

quality materials. This will certainly be affecting low quality mixed paper grades<br />

destined for the export market, in turn, tending to encourage collectors to consider<br />

quality more closely than they might hitherto have done.<br />

However, the levy has raised revenues, which are paid into an Environment Fund. This<br />

was established by the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Amendment) Act 2001 (No.36 <strong>of</strong> 2001)<br />

and is managed and controlled by the Minister for the Environment and Local<br />

Government. The fund was established with effect from 17 th July 2001. The details <strong>of</strong><br />

how the Environmental Fund 2006 was spent on waste prevention and recycling is<br />

outlined below.<br />

The proceeds from both the landfill levy and the plastic bag levy, collected by local<br />

authorities, are paid into the fund and the money is used for a range <strong>of</strong> measures<br />

including programmes and schemes to prevent or reduce waste, operation <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

recovery activities, litter prevention, environmental partnership projects and<br />

environmental awareness, education and training.<br />

11.6.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

There are no statistics available which would allow for a confident prediction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

influence <strong>of</strong> the waste levy on waste growth either in the household or non-household<br />

municipal waste streams. The rate <strong>of</strong> waste growth prior to the introduction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

landfill levy is not well known. As such, it is difficult to assess whether waste growth<br />

has been materially influenced by the levy. There are studies which have assessed<br />

the sensitivity <strong>of</strong> demand for waste services with respect to price, but these tend to<br />

suggest inelastic responses, so that with the effects on landfill prices being relatively<br />

small, the price effect would be expected to be similarly weak.<br />

We are not aware <strong>of</strong> any attempt to evaluate the environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> the<br />

expenditure <strong>of</strong> fund revenues, but they might reasonably be assumed to have been<br />

192<br />

29/09/09


positive. In 2007, <strong>of</strong> the €32,398,929 (as shown in Table 11-1 above) generated in<br />

income from the levy on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste, the following was spent on Prevention<br />

Initiatives:<br />

193<br />

� “<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and the National Market Development Group”,<br />

€1,518,213;<br />

� “Producer Responsibility Initiatives”, €905,793; and<br />

� “Environmental Awareness”, €1,615,332.<br />

The above figures illustrate that a large number <strong>of</strong> Environmental Awareness<br />

Campaigns and <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programmes, both nationally and within local<br />

authorities, have been supported through monies available from the Environmental<br />

Fund. Therefore this levy has indirectly influenced preventative initiatives in Ireland.<br />

11.6.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

In 2007, <strong>of</strong> the €32,398,929 (as shown in Table 11-1 above) generated in income<br />

from the levy on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste, the following was spent on recycling initiatives:<br />

� “<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> including Recycling Projects”, €17,246,428. This<br />

represents payments made to local authorities to assist in capital costs<br />

associated with the provision <strong>of</strong> waste management infrastructure; and<br />

� “Recycling Operational Costs”, €11,914,847. This represents payments made<br />

to local authorities to assist with the operational costs <strong>of</strong> recycling.<br />

This funding has assisted in the development <strong>of</strong> recycling facilities/infrastructure to<br />

have been put in place, having a positive impact on recycling in Ireland. The monies<br />

from this Environmental Fund are only made available to local authorities. The private<br />

sector is not eligible to receive support from the Environmental Fund.<br />

The main objective <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy is to encourage the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away<br />

from landfill and generate revenues that can be applied in support <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

minimisation and recycling initiatives. Figure 11-1 below details the trends in<br />

municipal waste recovered and disposed <strong>of</strong> from 2001 to 2007. Table 11-6 below<br />

details the trends in household waste managed from 2001 to 2007.<br />

From the table above it is apparent that the recycling rates have increased since the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy in 2002; this can in part be as a result <strong>of</strong> monies<br />

available from the Environmental Fund for the development <strong>of</strong> recycling infrastructure<br />

in local authorities’ functional areas, but as discussed above, more significant effects<br />

are likely to have been experienced through the change in landfill prices more<br />

generally (i.e. before the addition <strong>of</strong> the levy).<br />

The amount <strong>of</strong> household waste managed by local authorities and the waste industry<br />

has increased by 33% since 2001, while during the same period the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste recovered has increased four-fold since 2001, which reflects<br />

increases in recycling infrastructure. 215<br />

215 EPA (2007) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2006, Wexford: EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 11-1: Trends in Recovery and Disposal <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Table 11-6: Trends in Household <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Quantity<br />

Landfilled<br />

Quantity<br />

Recovered<br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

Produced<br />

Produced<br />

Average<br />

Landfill<br />

Gate Fee<br />

Landfill<br />

Levy<br />

194<br />

29/09/09<br />

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007<br />

1,254,857 1,294,061 1,231,109 1,214,908 1,198,504 1,379,246 1,200,980<br />

74,887 132,602 185,753 285,872 344,964 393,995 424,510<br />

1,329,744 1,329,744 1,426,662 1,426,662 1,416,862 1,416,862 1,500,780 1,500,780 1,543,468 1,543,468 1,543,468 1,773,24 1,773,242 1,773,24 1,625,490<br />

1,625,490<br />

€117 €139.50 €135 €112<br />

- - - - €15 €15 €20<br />

11.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The Environment Fund Accounts 2007 indicate an expenditure <strong>of</strong> €388,025 for<br />

“Environmental Levy Collection Costs”, this equates to less that 1% <strong>of</strong> the total<br />

income from the levy on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

Landfill Operators incur a cost in the compilation <strong>of</strong> the data and preparation <strong>of</strong><br />

returns to the <strong>Department</strong>. The cost <strong>of</strong> the establishment <strong>of</strong> necessary systems is not<br />

known.


11.8 Response from Public and Industry<br />

There is probably a low level <strong>of</strong> awareness, on the part <strong>of</strong> the public, regarding the<br />

levy. As the landfill levy is not a direct charge, but rather is subsumed in waste<br />

collection charges, the public in general would probably not be aware <strong>of</strong> its existence.<br />

While the landfill levy is stated on invoices, for businesses that produce little waste,<br />

the landfill levy is minimal. For an <strong>of</strong>fice, the average landfill levy on an invoice may<br />

be an integer number <strong>of</strong> euros per month.<br />

It seems that the landfill levy is very much obscured from view as it remains<br />

(currently) a small part in the total costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling (refer to Table 11-3 above).<br />

Furthermore, the link between charging households and the landfill levy is not a direct<br />

one, even where collectors make use <strong>of</strong> weight-based charging. For example, Indecon<br />

report that in Cork, weight-based charges were as high as €0.46 per kg <strong>of</strong> residual<br />

waste. 216 In some other cases where weight-based charges are in place, the link<br />

between charge rates and landfill gate fees appears somewhat more closely aligned,<br />

though this should not be taken as evidence <strong>of</strong> a firm link between the two.<br />

As detailed in the section above, the landfill levy revenues are directed into the<br />

Environmental Fund, which is made available to support local authority run projects in<br />

waste management. This arrangement has been highlighted by private sector<br />

operators as unfair, since in the Irish market, the private sector competes with local<br />

authorities. Therefore the Environmental Fund potentially becomes a source <strong>of</strong><br />

competitive advantage for local authorities.<br />

11.9 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

As far as municipal waste is concerned, the levy has probably had very limited impact<br />

on technical change and innovation. Weighbridges at landfill sites were required in<br />

order to manage the landfill levy but by 2002 most landfill sites had already installed<br />

weighbridges as a requirement <strong>of</strong> waste licences granted by the EPA. The<br />

Environmental Fund might have achieved more in this regard.<br />

11.10 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The landfill levy is paid by the contractor delivering waste to the landfill. Costs are<br />

ultimately passed on directly to those producing the waste. In the case where pay by<br />

weight collection systems are in place, costs can be transmitted more directly.<br />

The low level <strong>of</strong> the levy almost certainly implies that whilst the levy might have the<br />

potential to be regressive, social and distributional consequences are likely to be<br />

minimal.<br />

216 Indecon <strong>International</strong> in association with the Institute <strong>of</strong> Local Government Studies at University <strong>of</strong><br />

Birmingham (2006) Indecon <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Local Government Financing, Report Commissioned by the<br />

Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government.<br />

195<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


11.11 Complementary Policies<br />

In addition to the Landfill Levy, an environmental levy on plastic bags has been<br />

introduced. The proceeds <strong>of</strong> both the Environmental Levy on the supply <strong>of</strong> plastic<br />

bags (collected by the Revenue Commissioners) and the Environmental Levy on the<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste (collected by the Local Authorities) are paid into an Environment<br />

Fund which is used for a range <strong>of</strong> waste prevention schemes.<br />

The levy ought to complement pay-by-use schemes, since the rationale for charging<br />

for refuse collections is strengthened where disposal costs are higher. However, it<br />

should be recognised that there is not necessarily a direct link between residual<br />

waste disposal / treatment costs and the marginal rates charged by collectors for the<br />

residual waste collection system. Evidently, the link is less likely to be a strong one<br />

where the charges are not based upon weight.<br />

11.12 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

An earlier report by Eunomia assessed the externalities associated with Landfill,<br />

Incineration and MBT. 217 The results from that report are shown in Table 11-7.<br />

Elsewhere within these Annexes, we have also assessed the externalities from landfill<br />

and other residual waste treatment options (see Annex 63.0).<br />

Table 11-7: Externalities from Landfill, Incineration and MBT<br />

Landfill Landfill Incineration Incineration MBT<br />

MBT<br />

Direct emissions non-GHG related €2.64 €23.51 0.49<br />

Direct emissions GHG related €59.13 €28.71 15.62<br />

Total Direct Emissions €61.78 €52.22 €16.11<br />

Offsets GHG related -€1.60 -€6.79 -€4.72<br />

Offsets non-GHG -€2.95 -€9.61 -€6.18<br />

Total Offsets -€4.55 €4.55 -€16.40 €16.40 -€10.90 €10.90 €10.90<br />

Net Environmental damages €57.23 €35.82 €5.22<br />

Disamenity €4.25 €14.30 €9.28<br />

Total External Costs €61.48 €50.12 €50.12 €14.49 €14.49<br />

€14.49<br />

The results indicate that the current level <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy is – subject to the<br />

assumptions used - well below the current level <strong>of</strong> the levy. They also show that other<br />

residual waste treatment options should be subject to non-zero, though lower, levies.<br />

The first best option would be to internalise these externalities, and hence, limit<br />

demand for landfill. Equally, the first best option would be to internalise externalities<br />

<strong>of</strong> all management options, but first best options in respect <strong>of</strong> recycling are generally<br />

not available, and the second best option would be an implied subsidy for recycling<br />

activities, 218 which few Governments are prepared to sanction.<br />

217 Eunomia with Tobin (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Planning and Regulation in Ireland, Report for Greenstar.<br />

218 See, for example, for an estimate <strong>of</strong> external costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling, D. Hogg (2006) Impact<br />

<strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges, ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD; Sound<br />

Resource <strong>Management</strong> (2009) Environmental Life Cycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

196<br />

29/09/09


When the landfill levy was first introduced, landfill gate fees were on an upward trend.<br />

The landfill levy needs to be restructured to ensure that it targets the source <strong>of</strong> the<br />

externalities, for example a higher rate should be introduced for landfilling <strong>of</strong><br />

untreated waste, while a lower level should be put in place for landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

which has been stabilised. As it stands the existing landfill levy at €20 per tonne, is<br />

approximately 11.8% <strong>of</strong> the total landfill gate fee. Landfill levies in EU Member States<br />

are much higher at an average <strong>of</strong> €45 - €50 a tonne. The significance <strong>of</strong> the low level<br />

<strong>of</strong> the levy in the context <strong>of</strong> declining ex-levy gate fees is that the confidence in<br />

investing in alternatives is undermined as the ex-levy gate fee declines. Setting a<br />

higher levy, and giving certainty about future levels will encourage investment in<br />

alternatives in future.<br />

11.13 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

It is the function <strong>of</strong> each Local Authority to enforce and audit compliance with the levy<br />

requirement within its functional area. The levy is payable by weight which is recorded<br />

using weighbridges at the landfill facility. There is no evidence to suggest that the<br />

landfill levy is being evaded.<br />

Under Section 73 <strong>of</strong> the 1996 Act, a person who fails to pay levy which is due and<br />

payable under the forthcoming Regulations, or who fails to comply with a provision <strong>of</strong><br />

those regulations, would be guilty <strong>of</strong> an <strong>of</strong>fence. Penalties for an <strong>of</strong>fence under the<br />

1996 Act include fines <strong>of</strong> up to £10 million and/or imprisonment. In addition, in the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> a privately operated landfill, a conviction for an <strong>of</strong>fence under Section 73<br />

could lead the EPA to conclude that the relevant licensee (or licence applicant) was<br />

not a “fit and proper person” to hold a waste licence.<br />

11.14 Lessons Learned<br />

11.14.1 General Lessons<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the key lessons which the foregoing discussion seems to suggest is that the<br />

landfill levy has been too low to have a significant influence on behaviour, at least as<br />

far as municipal waste is concerned. The degree to which the levy has contributed to<br />

an increase in recycling must be questioned, given the role likely to have been played<br />

by the increases in (ex-levy) landfill gate fees since the mid-1990s, and the various<br />

policies in respect <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility. The effect <strong>of</strong> the levy in terms <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

prevention is likely to have been similarly weak, though no formal analysis has been<br />

conducted here.<br />

The rate <strong>of</strong> increase in the levy has been limited to €5 per tonne per annum. In terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling, inclusive <strong>of</strong> the levy, this would have done little more than<br />

maintain the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling in line with inflation. The reality, in recent years,<br />

appears to have been that the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling have been declining in real terms.<br />

Strategies with a Zero <strong>Waste</strong> Objective, Study <strong>of</strong> the Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> System in Metro<br />

Vancouver, British Columbia, Repoprt for Belkorp Environmental Services Inc. June 2009<br />

197<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


On the plus side, the levy is a simple measure and is thought to be relatively easy to<br />

enforce. Political backing for its implementation was important in pre-implementation<br />

stages. Future changes expected are an increase in the levy and broadening <strong>of</strong> its<br />

scope. Indeed, the EPA, in the National <strong>Waste</strong> Database Report, 2006, considered<br />

that:<br />

198<br />

29/09/09<br />

“the use <strong>of</strong> economic and policy instruments such as increasing the landfill<br />

levy and banning untreated waste from landfill should be immediately<br />

considered as it will present the strongest possible economic signal to the<br />

private waste industry to seek alternative outlets”.<br />

Most commentators recognise the need for an increased levy. The EPA, as one <strong>of</strong> its<br />

ten recommendations for change, suggests that: 219<br />

A higher landfill levy would increase the incentive to divert wastes to<br />

alternative treatments. Revenue from the increased levy could fund initiatives<br />

that specifically target OFBMW diversion and treatment.<br />

It goes on to say:<br />

A landfill levy specifically targeting OFBMW would rebalance the economics<br />

towards OFBMW treatment rather than disposal<br />

Such a levy would be difficult to design in the general sense, but the sentiment<br />

reflects the fact that the majority <strong>of</strong> the known externalities appear to be associated<br />

with methane releases, these being driven by the biodegradable waste component <strong>of</strong><br />

landfilled materials.<br />

219 EPA (2008) Hitting the Targets for Biodegradable Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>: Ten Options for Change,<br />

Wexford: EPA.


12.0 Producer Responsibility, Packaging - Ireland<br />

12.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The introduction <strong>of</strong> Producer Responsibility in relation to packaging in Europe was<br />

brought about through a number <strong>of</strong> Council Directives including; the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Directive (Council Directive 94/62/EC), Council Directive 2004/12/EC and Council<br />

Directive 2005/20/EC, both <strong>of</strong> which amend the 1994 Directive.<br />

In Ireland, the requirements <strong>of</strong> the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directive (Council Directive<br />

94/62/EC) were first introduced through the “1997 Packaging Regulations” (S.I. No.<br />

242 <strong>of</strong> 1997) and the “1998 Packaging Amendments Regulations” (S.I. No. 382 <strong>of</strong><br />

1998), both <strong>of</strong> which are now revoked in legislation.<br />

Following on from these, the existing Irish legislation was updated and replaced<br />

through the introduction <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Packaging) Regulations, 2003<br />

(S.I. No. 61 <strong>of</strong> 2003). The 1997 regulations (and 2003 regulations which replaced<br />

them) place primary obligations on all producers 220 <strong>of</strong> packaging waste to:<br />

199<br />

� To separate certain ‘specified categories’ (‘glass, aluminium, steel, paper and<br />

fibreboard, plastics, wood and textiles, or such other categories as may be<br />

specified by the Minister from time to time’) <strong>of</strong> waste packaging at source into<br />

segregated waste streams to allow for the collection by or on the behalf <strong>of</strong> the<br />

producer, or by a recovery operator 221 for the purposes <strong>of</strong> recycling and<br />

recovery; and<br />

� Ensure that producer packaging waste other than specific categories,<br />

including back door waste, is collected by or on the behalf <strong>of</strong> the producer, or<br />

by a recovery operator for the purposes <strong>of</strong> treatment, recovery or disposal.<br />

The 2003 Regulations (and 1997 Regulations) effectively prohibit the landfilling, from<br />

commercial sources, <strong>of</strong> such ‘specified categories’ <strong>of</strong> waste packaging.<br />

The 2003 Statutory Instrument came into effect on 1 st March 2003, and was<br />

introduced for the purposes <strong>of</strong> giving effect in Ireland to the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Directive (Council Directive 94/62/EC) and to set the legislative target in Ireland for<br />

220 “Producer” is specified, under and in accordance with section 27 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act,<br />

1996 (No. 10 <strong>of</strong> 1996) as amended by the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Amendment) Act, 2001 (No. 36 <strong>of</strong><br />

2001) to mean a person who, for the purpose <strong>of</strong> trade or otherwise in the course <strong>of</strong> business, sells or<br />

otherwise supplies to other persons packaging material, packaging or packaged products, and<br />

“produce” shall be construed accordingly.<br />

221 Recovery Operator” means (a) a local authority or other person engaged in waste recovery or waste<br />

collection for the purposes <strong>of</strong> recovery, subject to that person having obtained all necessary licences or<br />

permits required under the Act, or (b) a major producer when acting in accordance with the exemption<br />

from the requirement to hold a permit when collecting packaging waste in accordance with article<br />

22(e) <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Collection Permit) Regulations, 2001 (S.I. No. 402 <strong>of</strong> 2001), or with<br />

any regulation replacing or amending that article.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


the recovery <strong>of</strong> 50% <strong>of</strong> packaging waste by end 2005. This legislation was further<br />

amended in the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Packaging) Regulations, (S.I. No 871 <strong>of</strong> 2004).<br />

Council Directive 2004/12/EC was introduced at European level, to amend the<br />

original Directive 94/62/EC on packaging and packaging waste. In 2006, Irish<br />

legislation was aligned with this through the introduction <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

(Packaging) (Amendment) Regulations (S.I. No 308 <strong>of</strong> 2006). The 2006 Statutory<br />

Instrument introduced material-specific recycling targets, to be achieved in Ireland by<br />

end 2011 and the updated EU packaging waste recovery targets <strong>of</strong> 60% <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

(with 55% by way <strong>of</strong> recycling).<br />

The most recent legislation to come into play in Ireland with respect to the Producer<br />

Responsibility elements <strong>of</strong> the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directives is the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

(Packaging) Regulations (S.I. No. 798 <strong>of</strong> 2007). All producers, including retailers,<br />

participating in the placing <strong>of</strong> packaging on the Irish market, must segregate the<br />

packaging waste arising on their own premises into specified waste streams (i.e.<br />

waste aluminium, fibreboard, glass, paper, plastic sheeting, steel and wood) and have<br />

it collected by authorised recovery operators for recycling. The regulations consolidate<br />

the existing regulations <strong>of</strong> 2003 as well as the amending regulations <strong>of</strong> 2004 and<br />

2006 respectively to bring improved clarity, transparency and accessibility to the<br />

packaging waste regulatory regime. The principal articles <strong>of</strong> the regulations came into<br />

effect on the 31 st March 2008.<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> the measures in the 2007 Statutory Instrument, there has been a change<br />

in the ‘Major Producer’ category, and a reduction in the de minimis threshold (one <strong>of</strong><br />

the thresholds to determine ‘Major Producer’ status) from 25 tonnes to 10 tonnes,<br />

following on from the higher packaging recycling and recovery targets that have to be<br />

achieved under Directive 2004/12/EC. As a result this will result in bringing more<br />

businesses into the ‘obligated producer’ category.<br />

It is worth noting that Ireland received a derogation within the implementation<br />

deadlines, in relation to recycling and recovery targets set down at European level in<br />

the original Directive, only having to achieve at least 25 per cent recovery by 2001<br />

and 50 per cent recovery by 2005. This was in order to allow for the development <strong>of</strong><br />

required (recycling and recovery) waste management infrastructure.<br />

12.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

Packaging waste policy in Ireland is contained, in the most part, within the packaging<br />

regulations described in the Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> Section above, which have been brought<br />

into force through the introduction <strong>of</strong> legally binding Statutory Instruments. Within the<br />

area <strong>of</strong> packaging waste policy, Ireland has followed the requirements set down in a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> European Council Directives. The policy elements in Ireland did not<br />

develop independently, and until recently, policy had been introduced entirely in a<br />

reactive manner to the binding requirements <strong>of</strong> European legislation.<br />

The individual European Council Directives and Irish Statutory Instruments are listed<br />

in the section above. It may be noted that the main driving elements behind the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> the measures in the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directives were focused on the<br />

recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> packaging materials and all <strong>of</strong> the binding targets to date<br />

that have been set a European level have focused on recycling and recovery targets.<br />

200<br />

29/09/09


Although the European legislation does mention minimisation <strong>of</strong> packaging material<br />

use and volumes, this was not translated into specific targets in relation to the<br />

prevention <strong>of</strong> packaging at source with implementation deadlines as had been done<br />

for recycling and recovery.<br />

12.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The original Statutory Instruments were introduced in Ireland in 1997 and 1998, as a<br />

means <strong>of</strong> transposition <strong>of</strong> the 1994 European Directive, and therefore the<br />

background <strong>of</strong> the policy framework has been in place for 10 years. The 1997 and<br />

1998 regulations were replaced in law in Ireland by the 2003 regulations and then<br />

further amended in 2004. Most recently, the waste packaging policy was<br />

consolidated in the 2007 Regulations, which came into effect on 31st March 2008.<br />

12.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

12.4.1 <strong>Policy</strong> and Transposition <strong>of</strong> Regulations in Ireland<br />

Overall waste management is developed by the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment<br />

Heritage and Local Government (DoEHLG). Within the area <strong>of</strong> packaging waste, the<br />

DoEHLG are also the government body, which approves the application <strong>of</strong> Compliance<br />

Schemes/Compliance Bodies, <strong>of</strong> which to date only one has been approved in<br />

Ireland, namely Repak.<br />

12.4.2 Implementation and Administration <strong>of</strong> the Regulations<br />

The DoEHLG are involved in the implementation <strong>of</strong> the packaging regulations, both<br />

through being the responsible body for the transposition <strong>of</strong> the European legislation<br />

into Irish law, and in terms <strong>of</strong> the interaction they engage in with the Repak<br />

Compliance Scheme. Within this framework, the DoEHLG are also the body to which<br />

feedback and consultation is returned for the on-going operation and performance <strong>of</strong><br />

the regulations. As part <strong>of</strong> this function, the department undertook consultation prior<br />

to the drafting <strong>of</strong> the replacement 2003 Packaging Regulations. Most recently, the<br />

DoEHLG undertook Regulatory Impact Analysis in relation to the introduction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

2007 <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Packaging Regulations (S.I. No. 798 <strong>of</strong> 2007).<br />

Repak, as the operator <strong>of</strong> the only approved compliance scheme, is responsible for<br />

the administration and demonstration <strong>of</strong> compliance for participating companies,<br />

through funding from packaging levies, via its participating companies <strong>of</strong> the scheme,<br />

through management <strong>of</strong> the reporting at a national level from their members to the<br />

EPA and through the dissemination to members <strong>of</strong> information on compliance and<br />

innovation.<br />

At a local level, the individual Local Authorities are involved in implementation<br />

through the provision <strong>of</strong> information on packaging regulations to producers and<br />

recovery operators within their administrative area, and through the receipt <strong>of</strong><br />

reporting from producers and recovery operators, where those companies are not<br />

demonstrating compliance through membership <strong>of</strong> the Repak scheme (Self<br />

Compliers).<br />

201<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


As a result <strong>of</strong> the various organisations involved at an administrative level (Self<br />

Compliers, Repak and Local Authorities), the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)<br />

takes a coordinating role in the reporting <strong>of</strong> waste packaging data. The data are<br />

collected from all <strong>of</strong> these organisations, along with further data from the public<br />

(Local Authority) and private operators <strong>of</strong> waste recycling, recovery and disposal<br />

facilities. The EPA reports on packaging consumption, recycling and recovery rates to<br />

the DoEHLG and to the public.<br />

The EPA has a supervisory role over Local Authorities under the EPA Act, which is<br />

provided through the EPA’s Office <strong>of</strong> Environmental Enforcement and through the<br />

EPA/Local Authority ‘Packaging Enforcement Network’, an enforcement group chaired<br />

by the Office <strong>of</strong> Environmental Enforcement <strong>of</strong> the EPA and including enforcement<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficers from Local Authorities.<br />

The EPA also has an advisory role in the development <strong>of</strong> research, the generation <strong>of</strong><br />

national reviews and the production <strong>of</strong> guidance in best practice and expertise within<br />

the area <strong>of</strong> waste management and waste prevention. The EPA provides this guidance<br />

through its “Core Prevention Team”.<br />

Regulatory Regulatory Enforcement<br />

Enforcement<br />

Local Authorities are responsible for the enforcement <strong>of</strong> the regulations within their<br />

individual functional areas. The powers <strong>of</strong> the Local Authorities include the power to:<br />

202<br />

� Enter and inspect a premises;<br />

� Serve a notice on an individual or company and require the production/ or<br />

pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> compliance through information and documentary evidence; and<br />

� Take summary proceedings for an <strong>of</strong>fence, and in the case <strong>of</strong> prosecution,<br />

recover the cost <strong>of</strong> the proceedings from the <strong>of</strong>fender.<br />

Local Authorities are responsible for the permitting <strong>of</strong> recycling and recovery facilities<br />

located within their administrative area along with the permitting <strong>of</strong> the collection and<br />

transportation <strong>of</strong> recycled and recovered waste.<br />

The EPA is responsible for licensing the major recovery operators. The EPA has<br />

supervisory control over all local authorities under Section 63 <strong>of</strong> the Environmental<br />

Protection Agency Act, 1992 and has been assigned a role in producer responsibility<br />

on a range <strong>of</strong> waste streams, including packaging.<br />

As mentioned in the introduction, the main driver within the packaging regulation<br />

framework to date has been in the generation <strong>of</strong> recycling and recovery targets.<br />

While these mandatory targets continue to be <strong>of</strong> importance, attention is now<br />

beginning to focus on Packaging Prevention as the means by which to effect a change<br />

in future packaging trends.<br />

The EPA’s Core Prevention Team has initiated a project to search for all newly<br />

obligated producers in order to directly alert them to their obligations under the<br />

packaging waste regulations and to assist local authorities in their enforcement<br />

efforts.<br />

Responsibilities for the packaging system are summarised in Table 12-1.<br />

29/09/09


Table 12-1: Distribution <strong>of</strong> Responsibilities in the Packaging System<br />

203<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Activity Activity<br />

Responsible Responsible body<br />

body<br />

Transposition <strong>of</strong> directive into national legislation DoEHLG<br />

Monitoring <strong>of</strong> meeting targets (national + directive) DoEHLG<br />

Monitoring and control <strong>of</strong> compliance DoEHLG+ EPA<br />

Supplier <strong>of</strong> packaging data EPA (recyclers, local authorities, Repak)<br />

Collection Collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> packaging packaging waste<br />

waste<br />

Collection <strong>of</strong> packaging waste from households Local authorities/private operators/Repak<br />

Collection <strong>of</strong> packaging waste from industry/commerce <strong>Waste</strong> producers/private operators/Repak<br />

(Compliance administration with)<br />

Recycling and treatment <strong>of</strong> packaging waste<br />

Expenditures <strong>of</strong> packaging system covered by Repak + self-compliers<br />

Repak + self-compliers<br />

(not involved specifically in collection & treatment)<br />

Source: EEA (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems in Selected Countries: An<br />

EEA Pilot Study, EEA Report No 3/2005.<br />

It may be noted that the systematic administration for the compliance with recycling &<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> packaging waste is the responsibility <strong>of</strong> the individual self compliers, or<br />

<strong>of</strong> the compliance scheme where a Producer is a member <strong>of</strong> Repak. However, neither<br />

the individual Producer, nor the compliance scheme, undertake the direct collection<br />

or treatment <strong>of</strong> the packaging waste (though in principle, a Producer could do so).<br />

12.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

12.5.1 General Requirements <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Regulations – Producer<br />

Responsibility Obligations<br />

As mentioned in the section on <strong>Policy</strong> Context, as a result <strong>of</strong> the 2003 Regulations<br />

(and the revoked 1997 Regulations), all producers, including retailers, participating in<br />

the placing <strong>of</strong> packaging on the Irish market, must:<br />

� Segregate the packaging waste arising on their own premises into specified<br />

waste streams (i.e. waste aluminium, fibreboard, glass, paper, plastic<br />

sheeting, steel and wood); and<br />

� Have it collected by authorised contractors for treatment and recycling or<br />

recovery.<br />

A producer must identify their status under the Irish regulations, in terms <strong>of</strong> being<br />

either a ‘Producer’ or a ‘Major Producer’, as Major Producers have additional<br />

responsibilities under the regulations. As a result <strong>of</strong> the changes in Ireland brought<br />

into place by the 2007 Regulations, the ‘Major Producer’ category has been revised,<br />

so that:<br />

A ‘Major Producer’ is a producer with an annual turnover in excess <strong>of</strong><br />

€1,000,000 and and where the aggregate weight <strong>of</strong> packaging supplied exceeds<br />

10 tonnes in a calendar year.


Therefore, where turnover is less than €1,000,000 per annum, or where the weight <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging supplied is less than 10 tonnes, this person automatically is not a ‘major<br />

producer’, so it is defined a ‘producer’ if it supplies etc. packaging. Such ‘Producer ‘Producers’ ‘Producer<br />

have a number <strong>of</strong> obligations, including the need to:<br />

204<br />

� Declare its status as a ‘producer’ to the relevant Local Authority;<br />

� Separate all packaging waste from other waste, without contamination;<br />

� Arrange for the collection <strong>of</strong> the packaging waste by a permitted collector (or or<br />

for the supplier to ‘take back’ the packaging);<br />

� Ensure the waste collector is permitted for collection and and and for the final<br />

consignment destination;<br />

� Provide weights <strong>of</strong> the packaging materials supplied to trade customers, if<br />

requested; and<br />

� Facilitate the Local Authority in confirming its compliance, and with conducting<br />

any inspections.<br />

Producers are not themselves confronted with targets for recycling and recovery.<br />

Rather, their obligations relate more to their own waste management arrangements<br />

and their reporting. As such, whilst, in principle, a Producer could join the Repak<br />

compliance scheme, it is not immediately obvious what would be gained from doing<br />

so.<br />

‘Major Producers’ can either ‘Self Comply’ or join the Compliance Scheme, Repak.<br />

They have additional obligations to those <strong>of</strong> producers, set out under Articles 10-16<br />

and 25 <strong>of</strong> the Regulations, though these can be discharged by an approved body, <strong>of</strong><br />

which Repak is the only one in Ireland. Crucially, major producers are those who are<br />

required to demonstrate that (Article 11(2)):<br />

29/09/09<br />

(2) On and from the 31st day <strong>of</strong> December 2008, a major producer who is an<br />

importer <strong>of</strong> packaged products or is a packer/filler shall take such steps as<br />

are necessary to ensure that in any quarterly period, the aggregate weight <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging waste which is accepted or, as appropriate, collected by that major<br />

producer for the purposes <strong>of</strong> recovery—<br />

(a) is not less than 60% <strong>of</strong> the aggregate weight <strong>of</strong> packaging material and<br />

packaging imported or packed/filled and supplied by that major producer in<br />

the preceding quarterly period, and<br />

(b) that a minimum 55% <strong>of</strong> the aggregate weight <strong>of</strong> packaging material and<br />

packaging imported or packed/filled and supplied by that major producer in<br />

the preceding quarterly period is recovered by way <strong>of</strong> recycling, and, where<br />

appropriate,<br />

(c) that a minimum—<br />

(i) 60% by weight for glass, and as appropriate,<br />

(ii) 60% by weight for paper and board, and as appropriate,<br />

(iii) 50% by weight for metals, and as appropriate,<br />

(iv) 22.5% by weight for plastics, and as appropriate,


205<br />

(v) 15% by weight for wood,<br />

supplied by that major producer in the preceding quarterly period is recovered<br />

by way <strong>of</strong> recycling.<br />

As stated above, ‘Major Producers’ may choose to discharge these obligations<br />

through Repak. However, where companies do not participate in the Repak scheme,<br />

they must demonstrate compliance directly to the Local Authority in their<br />

administrative area. Self-complying ‘Producers’ must fulfil their obligations in the<br />

following way:<br />

� Register with the relevant Local Authority as a Self Complier;<br />

� Pay an annual levy for the amount <strong>of</strong> packaging supplied;<br />

� Submit a proposal for packaging management at your premises;<br />

� Submit a quarterly report within 10 days <strong>of</strong> the end <strong>of</strong> each quarter, with<br />

information specified in the second schedule <strong>of</strong> the regulations;<br />

� Renew registration annually with annual results and an amended plan for year<br />

ahead;<br />

� Compile a new packaging management plan every three years;<br />

� Comply with their recycling obligations as listed above;<br />

� Accept packaging back from the public, including packaging purchased<br />

elsewhere, provided that packaging is dealt with at the premises;<br />

� Collect packaging back from trade customers within 1 week <strong>of</strong> request;<br />

� Hold documentary evidence for up to 3 years to prove accuracy <strong>of</strong> the<br />

reporting submitted;<br />

� Display required signage at the entrance to each premises; and<br />

� If an Importer/ packer/ 1st User – a minimum <strong>of</strong> 50% <strong>of</strong> the volume <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging introduced into the market in the previous quarter must be taken<br />

back.<br />

As mentioned below, the percentage tonnage <strong>of</strong> packaging waste not covered by the<br />

Repak scheme, and therefore coming under the category <strong>of</strong> Self Compliers, is<br />

estimated by Repak to be 43% <strong>of</strong> the tonnage <strong>of</strong> packaging material entering the<br />

waste stream for recycling and recovery. 222<br />

As a result <strong>of</strong> the 2007 regulations, the Local Authority registration fees for Self<br />

Compliers have been adjusted to reflect inflation. The fees can now be levied in the<br />

range from €500 up to a maximum <strong>of</strong> €15,000.<br />

222 <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> - Presentation to TOBIN Consulting Engineers.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


12.5.2 The Packaging Regulations “Essential Requirements”<br />

Article 9 <strong>of</strong> the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directive requires all packaging placed on the<br />

market in the EU to comply with ‘essential requirements’ set out in Annex II <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Directive. The Essential Requirements were transposed in Ireland on the 1 st<br />

December 1998 as part <strong>of</strong> an Amendment to the 1997 Packaging Regulations.<br />

The Essential Requirements outlined in these regulations can be summarised as<br />

follows:<br />

206<br />

� Packaging weight and volume must be reduced to the minimum necessary for<br />

safety, hygiene and consumer acceptance <strong>of</strong> the packaged product;<br />

� Hazardous substances and materials must be minimised as constituents <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging (Article 11 lays down specific limits on named heavy metals);<br />

� Packaging must be suitable for at least one <strong>of</strong> the following – material<br />

recycling, energy recovery or organic recovery; and<br />

� If reuse is claimed, packaging must be suitable for that purpose as well as for<br />

material recycling, energy recovery or organic recovery.<br />

The European Committee for Standardisation (CEN), which is a standardisation<br />

organisation, has created a number <strong>of</strong> standards in the area <strong>of</strong> packaging. These are<br />

effectively referred to under Part VI <strong>of</strong> the Irish Regulations, which states:<br />

29/09/09<br />

28. (1) Subject to sub-article (2), a producer shall not supply packaging or<br />

packaged products to other persons within the State unless the packaging<br />

concerned complies with the requirements <strong>of</strong> the Fourth Schedule.<br />

(2) Packaging shall be deemed to comply with the requirements <strong>of</strong> the Fourth<br />

Schedule if it complies with a European standard duly adopted, or a standard<br />

prescribed under section 29(4) <strong>of</strong> the Act, in relation to the requirements <strong>of</strong><br />

the Fourth Schedule.<br />

It was intended that the methodology within the standards would contain<br />

specifications that might allow validation <strong>of</strong> compliance with packaging regulations on<br />

a European wide basis. As the approach taken in creating the standards did not<br />

facilitate this, individual countries effectively need to develop strategies for<br />

compliance.<br />

Repak notes:<br />

“Companies in Ireland should demonstrate compliance by providing the Local<br />

Authorities with sufficient technical documentation for a period <strong>of</strong> up to four<br />

years from the date the packaging was placed on the market.<br />

Irish companies which import packaging or packaged goods from other EU<br />

member states should contact their suppliers to obtain the necessary<br />

information. Companies manufacturing packaging in Ireland or sourcing<br />

packaging from outside the EU should compile a dossier containing the<br />

necessary information. Repak suggests that companies use the CEN<br />

standards to compile the necessary information.


207<br />

Companies that supply packaging or packaged goods to customers in other<br />

member states, particularly in the UK or France, may receive requests for<br />

information from these customers.”<br />

Where packaged goods are found not to be in compliance, the goods could be<br />

removed from the market and the Local Authority can make a prosecution.<br />

Repak highlights that although EU countries including Ireland have transposed the<br />

Directive, <strong>of</strong> these countries, only France and the UK have specified a procedure<br />

which companies must follow to demonstrate compliance. 223<br />

12.5.3 Producer Responsibility - Participation via Repak Compliance<br />

Scheme<br />

Repak is the only approved Compliance Scheme in relation to packaging in Ireland.<br />

Members, through membership, effectively pass on responsibility to Repak for the<br />

recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> the packaging waste they are required to meet, with<br />

participating companies paying a fee for membership, based on their membership<br />

type. Repak estimates that in 2006, 57% <strong>of</strong> the waste packaging tonnage came<br />

within the remit <strong>of</strong> the compliance Scheme, with 43% being outside as Self Compliers.<br />

Repak’s members are <strong>of</strong> two types: 224<br />

� Regular members (854 members) are those companies that are importers or<br />

brand holders, and have primary packaging responsibility. They are required to<br />

submit statistics biannually and pay an average fee <strong>of</strong> € 12,500; and<br />

� Scheduled members (1,327 members) are smaller operators, who are not<br />

involved in the branding or importation <strong>of</strong> products. They are not required to<br />

submit statistics to calculate the fee element required annually, and instead<br />

pay an annual flat fee, based on their turnover. These include small retailers,<br />

<strong>of</strong>f licences, hotels, pubs, clubs and restaurants.<br />

The membership is split, so that 39% <strong>of</strong> the membership is made up <strong>of</strong> Regular<br />

members (involved in direct importation or branding), and this set within the<br />

membership makes up 95% <strong>of</strong> the income generated from membership fees. For the<br />

regular members, the fee is split within the 5 categories <strong>of</strong> producer/manufacturer,<br />

converter, brand holder/importer, distributor/wholesaler and retailer.<br />

223 The approach taken in the UK is not especially ‘hard line’. For a discussion, see Eunomia, The<br />

Environment Council, Oko Institut, TNO and Atlantic Consulting (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention:<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report for Defra, April 2007. It can also be argued that the<br />

different ways in which the requirements <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Directive are implemented do, themselves,<br />

have an impact on the extent to which producers are likely to minimise packaging. Other things being<br />

equal, the greater the proportion <strong>of</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong> compliance borne by the producers (as opposed to local<br />

authorities and the generality <strong>of</strong> households), the stronger will be the incentive to minimise packaging.<br />

In this respect, the UK approach has to be considered alongside the very low proportion <strong>of</strong> compliance<br />

costs borne by producers, which <strong>of</strong>fers somewhat limited (though non-zero) incentives for compliance<br />

(see also Annex 13.0).<br />

224 <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> - Presentation to TOBIN Consulting Engineers.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


There is a flat fee per tonne in four <strong>of</strong> these categories, while the brand holder/<br />

importer is charged a Material Specific fee, as shown in Table 12-2.<br />

Repak is concerned that the way in which the scheme is enforced is inadequate for<br />

the purposes <strong>of</strong> highlighting those who are not compliant with the scheme. This, they<br />

argue, places an additional burden on the scheme itself to ensure that the obligation<br />

for Ireland as a whole can be met. Effectively, the existence <strong>of</strong> non-compliers<br />

suppresses the number <strong>of</strong> possible Repak members, and increases the cost to those<br />

members (above those which would otherwise prevail) required to support the<br />

scheme, and in particular, to provide the required revenue for RPS payments.<br />

Table 12-2: Fee Structure for Repak ‘Regular Members’<br />

Activity Activity<br />

Cost Cost (cent/kilo cent/kilo cent/kilo) cent/kilo<br />

Fee Fee Fee type<br />

type<br />

Producer/Manufacturer 0.205 Participation fee<br />

Converter 0.205 Participation fee<br />

Brand holder/ importer Specific to material Material specific fee<br />

Distributor/ Wholesaler 0.205 Participation fee<br />

Retailer 0.410 Participation fee<br />

In this context, it can be noted that Repak estimates that the number <strong>of</strong> noncompliers<br />

was about 1,050 in 2001, declining to an estimated 700 in 2004. 225 It has<br />

been suggested that some <strong>of</strong> this reduction can be attributed to stepped-up<br />

enforcement activity by the authorities.<br />

12.5.4 Availability <strong>of</strong> Packaging Data<br />

As mentioned in Section 12.2 <strong>of</strong> this chapter, the manner <strong>of</strong> the transposition and<br />

administration <strong>of</strong> the policy in Ireland means that the regulations do not provide<br />

quantitative objectives or obvious indicators by which to enforce minimisation. The<br />

current regulations have, to date, primarily acted as a recycling policy. The data from<br />

the EPA and the packaging compliance scheme, Repak, can, however, still provide<br />

figures <strong>of</strong> total packaging waste tonnages, in terms <strong>of</strong> assessing waste packaging<br />

arisings.<br />

Monitoring <strong>of</strong> the compliance <strong>of</strong> producers with the packaging regulations is carried<br />

out through assessment <strong>of</strong> their reporting on packaging volumes submitted either<br />

individually as Self Compliers, or through reporting by the Compliance Scheme Repak.<br />

As identified above, and further below, Local Authorities also have the powers to<br />

make inspections <strong>of</strong> individual premises and to request the production <strong>of</strong><br />

documentary records to prove compliance.<br />

225 Repak (2008) Submission & Presentations on <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> -<br />

Presentation to TOBIN Consulting Engineers<br />

208<br />

29/09/09


Data from both Repak and self-compliers reporting to their Local Authority are both<br />

returned to the EPA as the overall agency collating the data.<br />

An EEA Report flags the methodology which has been used to generate packaging<br />

statistics: 226<br />

209<br />

“The packaging statistics are based partly on compositional analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

landfilled household and commercial waste and questionnaire surveys among<br />

recycling (and recovery) companies. In keeping with the need for continuous<br />

improvement, and to address concerns about the reliability <strong>of</strong> the<br />

methodology, the EPA is testing a new methodology. 70–80 % <strong>of</strong> the<br />

packaged goods consumed in Ireland are imported, mostly from the UK,<br />

showing that Ireland's estimated per capita packaging consumption, 40 %<br />

above that <strong>of</strong> the UK, may well be an overestimate. A consultancy study led by<br />

Perchards consultancy, London suggests that the previous methodology used<br />

in Ireland has resulted in some over-estimate <strong>of</strong> arisings. A research project is<br />

in progress with the aim <strong>of</strong> developing a methodology for determining<br />

quantities <strong>of</strong> packaging placed on the market”.<br />

It has also been flagged in the 2006 EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Report that: 227<br />

“It has been noted […] that there are concerns with regard to the classification<br />

by the waste industry <strong>of</strong> municipal waste being disposed at landfill. […] The<br />

EPA is committed to researching this issue in 2008 and ensuring that the<br />

landfill <strong>of</strong> waste is accurately and consistently reported.”<br />

This concern <strong>of</strong> the EPA’s has to be taken in context <strong>of</strong> the reporting being dependent<br />

on composition data to monitor the tonnages <strong>of</strong> packaging waste generated, with<br />

different compositions used for different waste streams.<br />

In the National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007 published at the end <strong>of</strong> 2008, the section on<br />

packaging waste makes the comment: 228<br />

“The new (municipal waste) composition studies also provide comprehensive<br />

information on the contamination <strong>of</strong> the different packaging waste streams.<br />

Up to 20%, or more in some cases, <strong>of</strong> the weight <strong>of</strong> packaging waste is food<br />

and food residues and these residues are discounted from the packaging<br />

figures on both the landfill and recovery side <strong>of</strong> the equation.”<br />

Whilst this might be scientifically accurate, it would also be incumbent on all parties<br />

to understand the level <strong>of</strong> contamination <strong>of</strong> packaging sent for recycling in order to<br />

ensure that the reported recycling rates are consistent with the deductions made for<br />

contamination. The issue <strong>of</strong> materials quality is one which, generally, is important for<br />

Ireland to address, especially in the context <strong>of</strong> its dependence on export markets for<br />

reprocessing <strong>of</strong> collected materials.<br />

226 EEA (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems in Selected Countries: An EEA<br />

Pilot Study, EEA Report No3/2005<br />

227 EPA (2007) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report Report 2006, Wexford: EPA.<br />

228 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report Report 2007, Wexford: EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


12.6 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

210<br />

� EPA/Clean Technology Centre (2002), ‘A Strategy for Developing Recycling<br />

Markets in Ireland’, Synthesis Report<br />

� EPA (2008) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme Fourth Annual Report<br />

2007/2008<br />

� Perchards, FFact <strong>Management</strong> Consultants and SAGIS Ltd (2004). Study on<br />

the progress <strong>of</strong> the implementation and impact <strong>of</strong> Directive 94/62/EC on the<br />

functioning <strong>of</strong> the internal market: Interim report. Volume 1: main report. Web:<br />

http://www.europa.eu.int/comm/enterprise/environment/interim_report.pdf<br />

� EEA (2005) ‘Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems in<br />

Selected Countries: An EEA Pilot Study’, EEA Report No 3/2005<br />

� DoEHLG (2007) ‘Market Development Programme for <strong>Waste</strong> Resources 2007<br />

– 2011’<br />

� Perchards (February 2008), ‘Report on Packaging Supply Chain (Packaging<br />

Prevention)’ – commissioned by Repak Ltd in association with the packaging<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Steering Group as part <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Prevention<br />

Programme 2007<br />

� Action Group on Recyclates (2008), ‘Action Group on Recyclates First Report’<br />

� DoEHLG (2006) ‘Statement on Regulatory Impacts’, Responses from 2006<br />

Consultation’<br />

12.7 Environmental Benefits<br />

12.7.1 Benefits in Terms <strong>of</strong> Prevention<br />

We are not aware <strong>of</strong> any study which looks at the extent to which the Regulations<br />

have:<br />

� Encouraged prevention / re-use; and / or<br />

� Encouraged switching from one packaging material to another.<br />

Over the period from 2001-2007, packaging waste quantities have grown at an<br />

average compound rate <strong>of</strong> 3.2%. The effect by material is quite different, with some<br />

materials showing much higher growth than others (see Table 12-3). This reflects the<br />

linked effects <strong>of</strong> changing consumption patterns and the effect <strong>of</strong> economic growth.<br />

29/09/09


Table 12-3: Average Compound Rate <strong>of</strong> Growth <strong>of</strong> Packaging by Material, 2001-2007<br />

Packaging Packaging Material Material Average Average Annual Annual Growt Growth Growt<br />

Rate Rate, Rate , 2001 2001-2007 2001<br />

2007<br />

Paper and Card 1%<br />

Ferrous 2%<br />

Glass 9%<br />

Aluminium -1%<br />

Plastic 2%<br />

Other Metals -32%<br />

Textiles -4%<br />

Wood 14%<br />

Others -3%<br />

Source: EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Reports, 2001 and 2007<br />

The materials showing positive growth rates are those which arise in largest<br />

quantities, and in absolute terms, the greatest growth has been seen in glass, wood<br />

and plastic (in that order). There is a suggestion that glass packaging – typically used<br />

for premium beverages – might have increased, possibly at the expense <strong>of</strong> growth in<br />

other packaging materials, as disposable incomes have increased.<br />

Repak provides data for a short period <strong>of</strong> time on EPA figures for packaging waste<br />

tonnages, and those for Repak members (see Figure 12-1).<br />

Figure 12-1: Trend in Tonnes <strong>of</strong> Packaging for Repak Members, Total Packaging<br />

Reported by EPA, and Retail Sales Volume Index<br />

It is not clear that the data enable one to conclude much other than that the quantity<br />

<strong>of</strong> packaging waste, as reported by the EPA, has fluctuated considerably over time. In<br />

the first year, there is a reported decline in EPA figures (-15%), but an increase in the<br />

tonnages reported by Repak Members (approx +7%). In the following year, growth<br />

rates are the same, but in 2006, growth appears lower in the Repak tonnages than in<br />

211<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


the EPA figures. Growth declines in the next year also for the Repak members. 229<br />

Latest EPA data suggests that the 2007 growth figure would be marginally less than<br />

the figure shown for Repak members. The period covered by this data is too short for<br />

one to draw any conclusive observations from it.<br />

The EEA identifies three packaging waste prevention measures which have been<br />

created within the policy framework to minimise packaging waste generation (see<br />

Table 12-4). 230 The producer responsibility requirements in relation to packaging<br />

separation and collection and the funding <strong>of</strong> packaging awareness raising campaigns<br />

are administrative measures identified in the report, along with the economic<br />

incentive provided by the plastic bag levy. The plastic bag levy is described in more<br />

detail in Annex 27.0. In relation to packaging waste prevention, the EEA report notes<br />

that:<br />

212<br />

29/09/09<br />

“The plastic bag levy aims to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> plastic bags used and thus<br />

has a clear preventative objective.”<br />

Table 12-4: Intended Impacts <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> Measures in Ireland<br />

Measure<br />

Producer<br />

responsibility<br />

/Repak<br />

Awareness<br />

raising<br />

campaigns<br />

Year <strong>of</strong><br />

introduction<br />

1997<br />

Plastic bag levy 2001<br />

Landfill levy 2002<br />

Ban on landfilling <strong>of</strong><br />

particular wastes<br />

Obligation on<br />

producers to<br />

segregate<br />

packaging waste<br />

and have it recycled<br />

National <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Prevention<br />

Programme<br />

1999–2002,<br />

2003<br />

2003<br />

(some LA’s<br />

started earlier)<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

Purpose/targets<br />

To help member companies<br />

meet their packaging waste<br />

management obligations.<br />

To raise awareness.<br />

To reduce the number <strong>of</strong> plastic<br />

bags used annually.<br />

To achieve national targets for<br />

the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away<br />

from landfill towards recycling<br />

options.<br />

To divert waste away from<br />

landfill as there is a shortage <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill capacity.<br />

To ensure that packaging waste<br />

materials are not mixed and that<br />

all packaging waste generated<br />

by producers (as defined in the<br />

legislation) is recycled.<br />

To promote waste prevention<br />

and minimisation through a<br />

broad range <strong>of</strong> instruments.<br />

Relation to the objectives <strong>of</strong><br />

the directive<br />

To meet the recycling and<br />

recovery targets <strong>of</strong> the<br />

packaging directive.<br />

To promote a greater<br />

appreciation <strong>of</strong> the impact<br />

<strong>of</strong> personal behavior and<br />

highlight steps to reduce the<br />

impact on the environment.<br />

Prevention <strong>of</strong> plastics<br />

waste.<br />

To reduce final disposal <strong>of</strong><br />

waste and support the<br />

recovery/recycling targets.<br />

To reduce final disposal <strong>of</strong><br />

waste and support the<br />

recovery/recycling targets.<br />

To support<br />

recovery/recycling targets.<br />

Prevention <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

Source: EEA (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems in Selected Countries: An<br />

EEA Pilot Study, EEA Report No 3/2005.<br />

229 <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> - Presentation to TOBIN Consulting Engineers.<br />

230 EEA (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems in Selected Countries: An EEA<br />

Pilot Study, EEA Report No 3/2005


The EEA report identifies the role <strong>of</strong> the compliance scheme in packaging waste<br />

prevention:<br />

213<br />

“The weight-based Repak fee is an incentive for prevention, since it makes<br />

companies responsible for the amount <strong>of</strong> packaging placed on the market”.<br />

A stimulus for packaging minimisation and prevention also comes from internal cost<br />

reduction assessments undertaken by companies proactively. Repak provides<br />

guidance to its members with regard to packaging reduction and prevention.<br />

The incentives for companies to reduce and minimise packaging come both from the<br />

regulatory side in terms <strong>of</strong> the fees associated with packaging regulations compliance<br />

and from the basis <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it saving and cost effectiveness <strong>of</strong> their operations.<br />

The National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention programme is described in more detail in Annex 18.0.<br />

Under the auspices <strong>of</strong> the overall EPA waste prevention programme, the EPA and<br />

Repak launched The Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme (PWPP) in 2007. The<br />

Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme was announced as having an initial<br />

programme budget <strong>of</strong> €200,000, to be co - funded by the EPA and Repak, with the<br />

objective <strong>of</strong> the programme being to help Irish industry reduce the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging on their products.<br />

The proposed measures within the EPA/ Repak Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

Programme were detailed in the press release announcing the launch <strong>of</strong> the<br />

programme: 231<br />

� A series <strong>of</strong> awareness raising seminars;<br />

� A what is best practice packaging website;<br />

� A supply chain benchmarking study;<br />

� Exemplar best practice case studies;<br />

� Consumer research study on packaging preferences and purchase behaviour;<br />

� Packaging Design Awards aimed at promoting examples <strong>of</strong> best practice;<br />

� Development <strong>of</strong> a carbon footprint calculator for member companies; and<br />

� Development <strong>of</strong> a interactive householder carbon footprint calculator.<br />

We understand that the Programme is currently suspended due to lack <strong>of</strong> funding.<br />

The absence <strong>of</strong> packaging prevention objectives being identified in national policy<br />

creates difficulties at the level <strong>of</strong> Local Authority regulation in that enforcement<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficers do not have a straightforward set <strong>of</strong> criteria for enforcement activities against<br />

which they could take action – whilst it is not part <strong>of</strong> the packaging regulations policy,<br />

it is nevertheless important to highlight the existence <strong>of</strong> the EPA/Repak Packaging<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, as it is the only visible initiative within the<br />

administrative framework that specifically focuses on packaging prevention. Although<br />

231 Slattery Communications / Eoin Kennedy (14 March 2007) Repak and EPA Launch the First<br />

Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


this is laudable, its suspension due to lack <strong>of</strong> funding does raise the issue <strong>of</strong> how<br />

seriously the Essential Requirements aspect <strong>of</strong> the Directive have been taken in Irish<br />

policy. To the extent that producers are required to comply with the Essential<br />

Requirements, arguably, there should be no need for external funding sources to<br />

support this. It is the task <strong>of</strong> producers.<br />

In some European countries, e.g., Belgium, Slovakia and Spain packaging waste<br />

prevention and minimisation is set out in statutory targets. In the case <strong>of</strong> Spanish law,<br />

the target has been set by measuring the total quantity <strong>of</strong> packaging waste arising in<br />

a particular year against the total weight <strong>of</strong> packaged products consumed within the<br />

same year, against baseline year data <strong>of</strong> 1997 and 2001. 232 The report references<br />

an evaluation <strong>of</strong> packaging minimisation in Belgium, and notes that the quality <strong>of</strong> the<br />

packaging plans has improved as both the authors and authorities have gained<br />

experience over time.<br />

As stated above, we are not aware <strong>of</strong> any study which looks at the extent to which the<br />

Regulations have encouraged (or discouraged) prevention / re-use, and encouraged<br />

switching from one packaging material to another. The Repak figures give no reason<br />

to be confident <strong>of</strong> a discernible influence on the rate <strong>of</strong> growth in packaging over<br />

time, but properly, this would need to be considered against a possible counterfactual<br />

(no policy) in order for one to be clear about the extent to which the Regulations<br />

themselves may have been responsible for changes. It seems reasonable to believe<br />

that a logical response <strong>of</strong> companies – whether self-compliers, or complying through<br />

Repak – would be to reduce the financial and other burdens implied by the<br />

Regulations by reducing, at the margin, the weight <strong>of</strong> packaging used. One exception<br />

might be self-compliers, to the extent that these might be companies who take in<br />

significant quantities <strong>of</strong> readily recyclable packaging and who find that this makes<br />

compliance relatively straightforward.<br />

To a degree, therefore, any analysis which purported to distinguish the performance<br />

<strong>of</strong> Repak companies, or ‘self-compliers’, from another group in respect <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

prevention performance might not be reflecting a causal connection between the<br />

route for compliance and the prevention performance. Rather, the direction <strong>of</strong><br />

causality might be the other way round (people who are more able to meet<br />

requirements with minimal changes in behaviour might be more inclined to opt for<br />

self-compliance).<br />

In a 2005 study, it was stated that: 233<br />

214<br />

29/09/09<br />

Repak — and Enterprise Ireland find that the intentions <strong>of</strong> the directive are<br />

not fully transposed, as prevention and reduction <strong>of</strong> packaging amounts are<br />

not included in the regulation.<br />

232 Perchards (2008) Report on Packaging Supply Chain (Packaging Prevention), Report<br />

Commissioned by Repak in conjunction with the Packaging Prevention Steering Group.<br />

233 EEA (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems in Selected Countries: An EEA<br />

Pilot Study, EEA Report No 3/2005.


The same study went on to highlight some difference <strong>of</strong> opinion between DoEHLG and<br />

Repak:<br />

215<br />

Repak gives the system's waste prevention a low rating, as does Enterprise<br />

Ireland, which points out that the weight-based payments give little motivation<br />

to reduce the volume <strong>of</strong> packaging produced, and that opportunities to benefit<br />

financially from packaging prevention and reduction strategies are not clear to<br />

companies. The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment argues that the scale <strong>of</strong><br />

membership fees has been designed to relate directly to the amount and type<br />

<strong>of</strong> packaging placed on the market. If less is placed on the market,<br />

membership fees will decrease correspondingly: an implicit waste prevention<br />

measure.<br />

This is <strong>of</strong> some interest as it supports the notion – as would appear to be the case,<br />

anecdotally, in other countries - that if the incentive for waste prevention is to hit<br />

home, the full financial responsibility for the obligation should rest with industry.<br />

Currently, this appears not to be the case with the existing compliance scheme, with<br />

collectors still facing a ‘non-zero’ net cost for collection <strong>of</strong> waste for recycling. The<br />

logical solution might be one where the full costs <strong>of</strong> an efficient recycling collection<br />

were borne by obligated producers. 234<br />

12.7.2 Benefits in Terms <strong>of</strong> Recycling<br />

The intended impact <strong>of</strong> the Irish Packaging Regulations on recycling to date has<br />

specifically been to increase the rate <strong>of</strong> packaging recycling in line/ in reaction to the<br />

binding European targets. The national packaging recycling targets are based on the<br />

tonnages recycled as a percentage <strong>of</strong> overall tonnages <strong>of</strong> waste packaging generated<br />

that year. In the time period since the introduction <strong>of</strong> objective <strong>of</strong> meeting the<br />

recycling targets have been met.<br />

Estimates <strong>of</strong> packaging consumption are based either on packaging data from Repak<br />

or on packaging data from local authorities collating data from self compliers i.e. the<br />

estimate <strong>of</strong> the tonnages <strong>of</strong> packaging waste consumption is based on the tonnages<br />

<strong>of</strong> packaging entering the waste stream for recovery.<br />

According to data provided by Repak, the packaging waste target <strong>of</strong> 25% <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

recycled in the year 2001 was met and exceeded (with 27% packaging recycled),<br />

while the target <strong>of</strong> 50% <strong>of</strong> packaging recycled in the year 2005 was met and<br />

exceeded (with 59% packaging waste recycled).<br />

In the National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007 published, the section on packaging waste makes<br />

the comment: 235<br />

234 It should be noted that this is one reason why the comparison <strong>of</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> compliance with the EU<br />

Directive targets in a study by the EEA should be questioned. The emphasis there was on costs born by<br />

compliance schemes. However, different Member States effectively require compliance schemes to<br />

cover a varying scope <strong>of</strong> the total costs <strong>of</strong> compliance. In some schemes, obligated companies pay for<br />

all packaging recovery, in others, they pay only to stimulate, at the margin, the additional packaging<br />

collection and reprocessing needed to meet a given target.<br />

235 EPA (2008) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report Report 2007, Section 5, Wexford: EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


216<br />

29/09/09<br />

“ … As a consequence <strong>of</strong> reduced landfill, accompanied by a large increase in<br />

recycling, the packaging recovery rate increased from 57.3% in 2006 to<br />

63.6% in 2007.”<br />

The data for packaging waste from the annual EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Database Reports<br />

are presented in Table 12-5 and in Figure 12-2. The following are observed:<br />

� An increase in the total tonnages <strong>of</strong> packaging waste generated from 2001 to<br />

2007 (an average compound rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> + 3.2 % for the period, or a 21%<br />

increase overall);<br />

� A fall in the total tonnages <strong>of</strong> packaging waste landfilled from 2001 to 2007<br />

(an average annual fall <strong>of</strong> 5.9%. or 30% for the whole period); and<br />

� An increase in the total tonnages <strong>of</strong> packaging waste recovered from 2001 to<br />

2007. The annual compound rate <strong>of</strong> increase has been 20.3%, a net change<br />

<strong>of</strong> over 300% for the period).<br />

Table 12-5: Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Generation, Disposal and Recovery, 2004 - 2007<br />

Year Year Year<br />

2001 2001 200 2002 200 200 200 2003 200 2004 2004 2005 2005 2006 2006 2007<br />

2007<br />

Gross<br />

quantity<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Quantity<br />

landfilled<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Quantity<br />

recovered<br />

(tonnes)<br />

872,917 899,125 1,006,287 850,911 925,221 1,028,472 1,055,952<br />

551,651 602,736 586,687 371,371 370,589 438,952 384,322<br />

221,266 296,389 419,600 479,540 554,632 589,519 671,630<br />

Source: EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Reports 2004, 2005, 2006 & 2007<br />

The changes in the management <strong>of</strong> waste are generally positive, though as<br />

mentioned above, any effect on waste growth is not so easy to discern, not least since<br />

the different materials have witnessed differing rates <strong>of</strong> growth (see above).<br />

The degree to which these changes in management can be attributed to the existing<br />

policy on packaging is unclear. Some interventions are likely to have had a significant<br />

impact. For example, following the introduction <strong>of</strong> the requirement for producers to<br />

sort packaging waste, the EPA reported: 236<br />

The recovery <strong>of</strong> packaging waste increased by 14.3% in 2004, due to the<br />

increased availability <strong>of</strong> mixed dry recyclables collections from households<br />

and increased obligations on commercial premises to segregate and recycle<br />

packaging waste. The largest fraction by weight recycled is paper and<br />

cardboard, followed by wood and glass. Since March 2003, producers <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging are obliged to segregate for recovery specified packaging waste<br />

236 EPA (2005) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2004, Wexford: EPA.


217<br />

materials at source, effectively banning the landfill <strong>of</strong> these materials. This is<br />

reflected most dramatically in an increase in the recovery rate <strong>of</strong> paper and<br />

cardboard, from 41% in 2003 to 70% in 2004.<br />

As noted in Annex 11.0, there have been significant increases in landfill gate fees<br />

over the period since the late 1990s. These will have driven increases in dry recycling<br />

as collectors seek to avoid the rising costs <strong>of</strong> disposal. The Repak RPS payments are<br />

not, however, as significant in the commercial sector as they are in the household<br />

sector. At present, the majority <strong>of</strong> packaging recycling is associated with nonhousehold<br />

waste, and here, the effect <strong>of</strong> rising landfill costs and improving prices for<br />

secondary materials are likely to have been more significant than the RPS payments.<br />

It seems reasonable, however, to believe that the Regulations have had a positive<br />

effect, albeit possibly only a marginal one, through the financial inducements to<br />

companies collecting packaging waste which Repak provides.<br />

Figure 12-2: Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Generation, Disposal and Recovery, 2004 - 2007<br />

Quantity (tonnes)<br />

1,200,000<br />

1,000,000<br />

800,000<br />

600,000<br />

400,000<br />

200,000<br />

0<br />

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Gross quantity Quantity landfilled Quantity recovered (tonnes)<br />

A National Strategy Group on Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling was set up in October 2004<br />

to engage in consultation on an on-going basis with stakeholders and to facilitate<br />

achievement <strong>of</strong> the targets <strong>of</strong> the packaging regulations. The Group is chaired by<br />

DoEHLG and Repak and includes representatives from Local Authorities, Producers,<br />

business organisations e.g. IBEC, the EPA, waste collectors and re-processors.<br />

Prior to the introduction <strong>of</strong> the 2007 regulations, consolidating the existing legislation,<br />

DoEHLG undertook a Statement on Regulatory Impacts <strong>of</strong> the draft <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Packaging) Regulations to assess the state <strong>of</strong> current implementation<br />

at that time, and to assess the pros and cons <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> further regulation.<br />

This Statement flagged the role <strong>of</strong> the Strategy Group, in being involved with<br />

reviewing the implementation and operation <strong>of</strong> the regulations and monitoring <strong>of</strong> the<br />

regulations. It indicated that the process <strong>of</strong> monitoring the regulations will be done


through the input <strong>of</strong> data from Repak and from national data complied by the EPA,<br />

and that the performance indicators to be used would be:<br />

218<br />

� The increase in levels <strong>of</strong> recovery/recycling;<br />

� The increase in the numbers in the compliance scheme or as Self Compliers;<br />

and<br />

� Increases in the roll out <strong>of</strong> required recycling infrastructure including bring<br />

banks etc.<br />

It is worthy <strong>of</strong> note that the requirements, upon producers, under Article 5 <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Regulations, to separate packaging relates to the sorting <strong>of</strong> material for ‘recovery’.<br />

This reflected the definition in the 2006 version <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive <strong>of</strong><br />

‘recovery’. So as to avoid the possibility that separately collected fractions <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging waste, that were intended to be recycled were subsequently sent for<br />

recovery at incineration plants, it would seem sensible to re-word this in the existing<br />

Regulations.<br />

12.8 Implementation Costs<br />

12.8.1 Implementation Costs <strong>of</strong> Packaging Recycling <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The implementation costs for setting up and operating the administrative measures<br />

primarily revolve around providing staff and training resources. The staffing resource<br />

is spread across all those organisations described in Section 12.4 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes.<br />

The staff required range across the regulatory and guidance authorities and<br />

organisations, from policy and guidance staff in DoEHLG and the EPA, to enforcement<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficers in the enforcement network <strong>of</strong> the EPA & Local Authorities, to technical and<br />

guidance staff in the EPA/Repak, to the project staff at the compliance scheme<br />

Repak, to external consultant auditors <strong>of</strong> the compliance scheme, to staff in<br />

stakeholder groups like the Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Association and IBEC.<br />

Local Authorities indicated during the 2006 consultation that there is an existing<br />

burden on their staffing levels with the current requirements <strong>of</strong> the regulations. 237<br />

They flagged that the reduction in the de minimis threshold would increase the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> companies in the ‘Major Producer’ category and which would place a<br />

resource burden on Local Authorities in meeting administration and enforcement<br />

requirements with the same number <strong>of</strong> staff.<br />

The EEA report notes:<br />

29/09/09<br />

“No specific estimates <strong>of</strong> the public authorities' administrative costs (general<br />

administration, monitoring <strong>of</strong> packaging and packaging waste, etc.) or the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> the self-complying companies are available.”<br />

Repak administers the monthly data processing and auditing <strong>of</strong> subsidy claims by<br />

Repak authorised service providers (Private and Public waste management collectors<br />

237 DoEHLG (2006) ‘Statement on Regulatory Impacts’, Responses from 2006 Consultation


and processors). In terms <strong>of</strong> the reporting and data returns requirements involved in<br />

the compliance scheme, the month to month data administration <strong>of</strong> scheme<br />

members is managed by Repak on behalf <strong>of</strong> scheme members.<br />

For those companies representative <strong>of</strong> the 43% <strong>of</strong> packaging currently not under the<br />

remit <strong>of</strong> the Repak scheme, these companies must undertake all <strong>of</strong> the<br />

administrative functions themselves, and individual Local Authority staff resources<br />

are required to be available to assess the packaging data and enforce compliance.<br />

In addition to the Statutory fees required to be paid, Producers may also incur fees in<br />

payment to Consultants, either in the production <strong>of</strong> packaging plans for the Local<br />

Authorities, or where a Consultancy report is produced in response to a request from<br />

a Local Authority as part <strong>of</strong> the process determining whether the operator comes into<br />

the Major Producer category. In the Consultation process mentioned above by the<br />

Strategy group, both the Local Authorities and representative <strong>of</strong> small businesses<br />

identified this potential additional cost as being a financial burden to small<br />

businesses.<br />

12.8.2 Establishment <strong>of</strong> the Market Development Programme<br />

The DoEHLG established the Market Development Group to develop and Implement<br />

the Governments Market Development Programme 2007 – 2011, to progress the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> new markets for recyclates. The waste management industry<br />

stakeholders have been concerned with the poor development <strong>of</strong> market outlets for<br />

recyclates in addition to the variation in market values. The objective given in the<br />

report for the programme is that: 238<br />

219<br />

“the Market Development Programme for <strong>Waste</strong> resources, for the first time,<br />

seeks to identify and address barriers to greater levels <strong>of</strong> reprocessing waste<br />

in Ireland” And “This programme sets out a specific set <strong>of</strong> measures through<br />

which greater levels <strong>of</strong> recycling can be achieved in Ireland which in turn will<br />

reduce our reliance on overseas infrastructure and provide greater incentives<br />

for waste recovery activities in the country”.<br />

Packaging materials recovered on behalf <strong>of</strong> Producers by private and public waste<br />

collection and treatment operators have a monetary value, which can be realised<br />

when the materials are recycled. The material values available to waste collection<br />

operators will influence the fees that they apply for the service they provide in<br />

accepting the materials from producers. When the income associated with selling<br />

recovered materials on the markets is low, this increases the net cost <strong>of</strong> providing<br />

collection services for recycling.<br />

The Market Development Programme 2007 – 2011 identified barriers experienced by<br />

waste management companies in the area <strong>of</strong> market development:<br />

� the existence <strong>of</strong> market limitations (e.g. a limited supply <strong>of</strong> recovered paper),<br />

limited market outlets within Ireland;<br />

238 DoEHLG (2007) Market Development Programme for <strong>Waste</strong> Resources 2007 – 2011.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


220<br />

� instability and price fluctuations <strong>of</strong> the markets for recyclable materials;<br />

� limited alternative outlets (in some cases due to quality requirements for<br />

potential outlet uses being undeveloped);<br />

� lack <strong>of</strong> approved existing standards for recycled waste packaging products;<br />

and<br />

� lack <strong>of</strong> financial support to businesses to extend capability for reprocessing <strong>of</strong><br />

materials.<br />

More recently, the DoEHLG has also administered the convening and meeting in<br />

November 2008 <strong>of</strong> the Action Group on Recyclates Markets 239 in communication with<br />

the IWMA:<br />

29/09/09<br />

“Arising from a significant collapse <strong>of</strong> prices in the recyclate market, the<br />

IWMA sought a meeting with the <strong>Department</strong> to highlight immediate concerns<br />

with regard to storage <strong>of</strong> materials. Following on from this the <strong>Department</strong><br />

issued a circular to local authorities setting out a range <strong>of</strong> permitting and<br />

licensing options for the industry, as outlined by the EPA.”<br />

This Action Group on Recyclates Markets is focusing on addressing current actions<br />

that may specifically be required in the current economic market environment, and in<br />

relation to compliance requirements in the context <strong>of</strong> difficult recyclates markets.<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the action points arising from the November 2008 meeting included:<br />

“In relation to markets, the Market Development Programme team will be<br />

asked to compile a database <strong>of</strong> outlets / companies that accept recyclates in<br />

Ireland to promote the movement <strong>of</strong> these goods”<br />

“The development <strong>of</strong> a national brokerage for recyclates to ensure that Irish<br />

companies have help in achieving better deals in world markets is to be<br />

examined”<br />

“The Market Development Programme work plan will be reviewed to take<br />

account <strong>of</strong> the need to provide high quality paper and plastic in order to<br />

secure markets, and the growing importance <strong>of</strong> developing an indigenous<br />

recycling industry”<br />

“An additional €2 million will be provided in 2009 to underpin the local<br />

authority recycling infrastructure and public confidence in recycling”.<br />

12.8.3 Packaging Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Measures<br />

Article 15 <strong>of</strong> the regulations effectively requires major producers to prepare plans<br />

which set out the measures to be taken to prevent or minimise packaging waste. This<br />

is one <strong>of</strong> the Articles which Major Producers are effectively exempted from through<br />

their membership <strong>of</strong> a compliance scheme. However, Part VI <strong>of</strong> the Regulations refers<br />

to the ‘Essential requirements <strong>of</strong> packaging’ and European standards, so that whilst<br />

239 DoEHLG (2008) Action Group on Recyclates Markets 1 st Report, December 2008.


Repak members, and non-major producers, are not bound by Article 15, self<br />

complying major producers are, and all producers are effectively required to assess<br />

packaging against the CEN Standard on Prevention (EN 13428:2000). Local<br />

authorities are responsible for enforcement <strong>of</strong> the Regulations, including this part <strong>of</strong><br />

them.<br />

The EPA’s Core Prevention Team, in conjunction with the DoEHLG and Local<br />

Authorities, is responsible for providing guidance on packaging waste prevention.<br />

At the compliance scheme level, Repak provides guidance and technical services to<br />

its members through its Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme and advertises this<br />

to its members. It notes that the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme is part <strong>of</strong><br />

the National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme administered by the Environmental<br />

Protection Agency (EPA) and is co-funded by the EPA with the support <strong>of</strong> the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage & Local Government.<br />

Repak also provides a packaging prevention service to its members, ‘Reduce and<br />

Save’, using the technical guidance and expertise <strong>of</strong> a packaging technologist.<br />

However, laudable as these measures are, it does not seem clear that the<br />

Regulations are being enforced as strongly as they might be, especially in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

waste prevention.<br />

12.9 Response from Public and Industry<br />

The response from Industry on the whole has been to comply with their<br />

responsibilities. Prior to March 2008, when the classification <strong>of</strong> Major Producer was<br />

changed, Repak members numbered 2,333, with the estimated number <strong>of</strong> selfcomplying<br />

companies being <strong>of</strong> the order 150. 240 These numbers will have changed in<br />

the wake <strong>of</strong> the drop in the de minimis thresholds.<br />

Industry stakeholders in the consultation process in the DoEHLG Statement <strong>of</strong><br />

Regulatory Impacts were concerned with the issue <strong>of</strong> cost implications associated<br />

with the change in the de minimis threshold under the revised packaging regulations.<br />

The industry stakeholders opposed to the change estimated that this could cost<br />

between €2,000 to €3,000 for a business in hiring consultancy firms to carry out<br />

work to assist in an assessment <strong>of</strong> packaging waste management and compliance.<br />

This was regarded by the industry stakeholders as an unnecessary financial burden,<br />

particularly on small businesses, given their scale <strong>of</strong> operation. 241<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> submissions were received and their comments summarised in the<br />

Statement on Regulatory Impacts produced by the DoEHLG. Some <strong>of</strong> these responses<br />

include:<br />

221<br />

“The proposed changes make self-compliance too onerous and unattractive<br />

an option for producers, thereby forcing them to join a compliance scheme. If<br />

240 Information from Repak presentation to Eunomia, February 2009.<br />

241 DoEHLG (2007) Statement on Regulatory Impacts, Strategy Group Consultation Responses 2006<br />

on 2007 Regulations.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


222<br />

29/09/09<br />

the self-compliance regime becomes too burdensome, the question has been<br />

raised as to whether this would be perceived as restricting competition,<br />

particularly given that only one compliance scheme has been approved under<br />

the existing Regulations (namely Repak)”;<br />

“The reductions in the de minimis threshold were unnecessary, having regard<br />

to existing and proposed recovery and recycling rates and would be<br />

disproportionately burdensome on small businesses, having regard to the<br />

contribution such reductions would make to increases in the recycling and<br />

recovery <strong>of</strong> packaging waste. In this context, the reductions proposed by the<br />

Strategy Group should be subject to Regulatory Impact Assessment (RIA) to<br />

quantify the impact on small and medium enterprises before a final decision<br />

is made on the matter; the <strong>Department</strong> should carry out this assessment”;<br />

“The de minimis concept was meant to exclude producers who place small<br />

amounts <strong>of</strong> packaging waste on the market”<br />

“Turnover threshold (at the time in 2006) <strong>of</strong> €1million and 25 tonne threshold<br />

are much lower than the corresponding de minimis thresholds in the UK”<br />

“If local authority registration fees (€15,000 max) can be adjusted by<br />

reference to the Consumer Price Index (CPI), this should also apply to the<br />

current de minims threshold”<br />

“There should be significant focus placed on small and medium sized<br />

enterprises in all education programmes operated by Repak, in particular<br />

programmes on waste prevention/minimisation”<br />

The EEA 242 Report cites that there may be queries in relation to the relative size <strong>of</strong> the<br />

compliance costs on smaller businesses and some <strong>of</strong> which have been raised by<br />

Repak in the consultation for that report:<br />

“Repak is concerned that standards <strong>of</strong> compliance are not equitable: not all<br />

major companies are obligated, and among those who are, some are getting<br />

away without paying. Moreover, self-complying companies may not be<br />

addressing the objectives <strong>of</strong> the directive”.<br />

The report also elicited some feedback in relation to the perceived functions <strong>of</strong><br />

administrative organisations:<br />

“As regards the institutional structures, DoEHLG, the Dun Laoghaire<br />

Rathdown county council and Enterprise Ireland generally find that there have<br />

been no major problems due to structural organisation. Repak, however, sees<br />

a problem with the responsibility being fragmented among central government<br />

and 34 politically independent local authorities, with the Irish EPA overseeing<br />

their actions. Repak also finds that packaging is given low priority since it only<br />

makes up about 1 % <strong>of</strong> total waste”.<br />

242 EEA (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems in Selected Countries: An EEA<br />

Pilot Study, EEA Report No 03/2005/


In their submission <strong>of</strong> information for this review by Repak noted: 243<br />

223<br />

“clearly a need for the adoption <strong>of</strong> a national strategy on packaging prevention<br />

and minimisation, with agreed targets, timelines, programme measures and<br />

implementing agency(ies)”<br />

The Repak submission notes a potential ‘dichotomy <strong>of</strong> roles’ in administration <strong>of</strong><br />

prevention activities and <strong>of</strong> the compliance scheme but notes:<br />

“In that regard, there is no reason why Repak could not continue to be the<br />

main implementing agency, providing adequate resources were made<br />

available, and that there was adequate transparency”.<br />

“The implementation <strong>of</strong> a national strategy will require adequate resources.<br />

While a more detailed implementation plan would identify a more precise<br />

budget, an annual operating budget <strong>of</strong> the order <strong>of</strong> two million euro is the<br />

minimum required to deliver a meaningful programme” And “Repak is already<br />

operating under financial constraints, both from its members (seeking<br />

reduced costs) and its operators (local authorities seeking extra funding). As<br />

such, the ability <strong>of</strong> Repak to fully resource the required programme is severely<br />

constrained.”<br />

In relation to the potential funding sources to be used to provide resources for<br />

packaging <strong>Waste</strong> prevention, the EPA notes in their National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2006, that<br />

with regard to packaging waste: 244<br />

and that:<br />

“Packaging waste recycling is strong and continues to grow. Addressing the<br />

growth in the use <strong>of</strong> packaging, as illustrated by the growth in packaging<br />

waste, should now become a new priority for Repak, as opposed to finding<br />

new, and more expensive, sources <strong>of</strong> packaging waste to recycle”<br />

“With the de minimus for major producers being reduced from 31 March<br />

2008, Repak will have many new members, representing a new source <strong>of</strong><br />

income to Repak”.<br />

12.10 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The key changes that have been associated with the Packaging Regulations are<br />

probably the changes in segregation activity undertaken by businesses and<br />

households, the changes in collection services <strong>of</strong>fered by waste companies and the<br />

increase in the infrastructure required to deal with the collected materials. However,<br />

as stated above, the degree to which this is directly traceable to the effects <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Regulations is not clear. High landfill gate fees might have been sufficient to<br />

stimulate part <strong>of</strong> the change, though perhaps not all <strong>of</strong> it.<br />

243 Repak (October 2008) Submission & Presentations on <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Policy</strong> - Presentation to TOBIN Consulting Engineers.<br />

244 EPA (2007) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2006, Wexford: EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Article 9.1 <strong>of</strong> EU Directive 94/62 on packaging and packaging waste requires<br />

Member States to ensure that with effect from 31 December 1997, packaging may<br />

be placed on the market only if it complies with all Essential Requirements. The<br />

Packaging (Essential Requirements) Regulations were introduced in Ireland in 1998<br />

as part <strong>of</strong> an amendment to the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Packaging) Regulations 1997.<br />

A Repak report <strong>of</strong> 2008 identifies the key decision makers within a number <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging supply chains and highlights both opportunities and obstacles for<br />

packaging prevention and minimisation. 245 The report examines a number <strong>of</strong><br />

common products and works back through the supply chain to identify the factors and<br />

dynamics <strong>of</strong> packaging decisions. This is done in order to enforce the notion that<br />

packaging can be kept to the minimum adequate amount to maintain safety hygiene<br />

and acceptance by the customer, as set out in the packaging Essential Requirements.<br />

The report notes also that reducing packaging also reduces the cost <strong>of</strong> procurement,<br />

fuel consumption and vehicle movements.<br />

The implementation and enforcement <strong>of</strong> the Essential Requirements aspects has not<br />

been a major thrust <strong>of</strong> the existing Regulations thus far.<br />

Repak’s submission and feedback in relation to packaging waste prevention is given<br />

in the subsection above on Responses from Industry. In their submission for this<br />

review Repak notes that:<br />

224<br />

29/09/09<br />

“The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage and Local Government, which is a<br />

member <strong>of</strong> the NSGPWR and participates in the Steering Group, has not<br />

adopted any formal policy or strategy. The only recent strategy measure<br />

adopted by the <strong>Department</strong> is to seek a voluntary packaging reduction<br />

agreement with the retail sector, as outlined above, but there is no clear<br />

evidence <strong>of</strong> any endgame or developed strategy in what it is that the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> is seeking to achieve from this measure”.<br />

As mentioned in the Section 12.7.1 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes, the manner <strong>of</strong> the<br />

transposition and administration <strong>of</strong> the policy in Ireland means that the regulations<br />

do not provide quantitative objectives or a structure or by which to enforce packaging<br />

waste prevention. Industry feedback seems to suggest, as mentioned above, that in<br />

its current form the current packaging policy has too loose a structure within which<br />

prevention measures can be administered and enforced.<br />

12.11 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The social and distributional consequences <strong>of</strong> the existing system depend upon a<br />

range <strong>of</strong> variables. These include:<br />

1. For businesses, the degree to which compliance costs are linked to the size <strong>of</strong><br />

business, or to its nature, this, in turn, depending upon the net effect <strong>of</strong>:<br />

245 Perchards (2008) Report on Packaging Supply Chain (Packaging Prevention), Report for Repak,<br />

February 2008.


225<br />

a. Direct costs <strong>of</strong> compliance (in respect <strong>of</strong> e.g. payments to Repak,<br />

additional time spent in managing waste, costs <strong>of</strong> any spatial<br />

requirements which may arise); and<br />

b. The effects on waste / resource management costs resulting from<br />

avoided disposal costs, including the extent to which the effects <strong>of</strong> RPS<br />

payments to collectors are passed through to businesses in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

cost savings; and<br />

c. The effect <strong>of</strong> the regulations on the net cost <strong>of</strong> packaging materials.<br />

2. For households, the degree to which:<br />

a. The RPS payments support the costs <strong>of</strong> collection (the net effect on<br />

collection costs); and<br />

b. Where PBU systems are in place, the nature <strong>of</strong> the benefits associated<br />

with avoiding disposal.<br />

We are not aware <strong>of</strong> any systematic attempt to understand the effect <strong>of</strong> these on<br />

different actors.<br />

In the DoEHLG Regulatory Impact Statement, it is suggested that there is a significant<br />

cost differential between the collection <strong>of</strong> packaging waste at commercial premises<br />

and that which takes place at households:<br />

“Domestic packaging waste is typically more expensive to collect/ recover<br />

than commercial packaging waste, with Repak estimating this cost to be<br />

higher by a factor <strong>of</strong> 7:1 and continuing to increase.”<br />

The differential is expected, but the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the ratio as suggested above seems<br />

rather high (and the costs net <strong>of</strong> revenues from material sales would be expected to<br />

vary with market conditions). This is not entirely in line with work carried out by<br />

RECOUP for WRAP on kerbside collection <strong>of</strong> plastic bottles, which indicates<br />

economies <strong>of</strong> scale in collection there<strong>of</strong>, leading to considerable reductions in the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> kerbside collections <strong>of</strong> plastic as the capture rate increases. 246<br />

It is noted in the DoEHLG Regulatory Impact Statement<br />

“The Strategy Group considered that it was appropriate that the base <strong>of</strong> major<br />

producers should be extended to assist in financing the extra tonnages that<br />

will arise in the domestic sector” and<br />

“The introduction <strong>of</strong> pay by weight and pay by use, coupled with the circa<br />

90,000 (2006 estimate) annual new house completions, have been among<br />

the main drivers underpinning this upward trend (in domestic recycling<br />

activity)”.<br />

246 See RECOUP (2005) Study to Identify Methods <strong>of</strong> Enhancing Local Authority Collection <strong>of</strong> Plastics,<br />

Report for WRAP, PLA022, May 2004.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


12.12 Complementary Policies<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> policies exist which complement the aims and objectives <strong>of</strong> the<br />

packaging regulations. These complementary policies include:<br />

226<br />

� Pay by use (where provision is made for separation <strong>of</strong> household packaging<br />

and dry recyclable waste);<br />

� The landfill levy; and<br />

� The plastic bag levy.<br />

Although not strictly speaking ‘a policy’ in the terms <strong>of</strong> this study, the National <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Prevention Programme is also <strong>of</strong> relevance.<br />

12.13 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> the polluter pays policy, the polluter is both the packaging producer, who<br />

has the final decision on packaging design, and the consumer, who makes the<br />

decision about purchasing the product. In principle, the mechanism in place ensures<br />

that producers pay for an undefined proportion <strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> recycling collections,<br />

with these being, to a degree, reflected in the prices paid by producers (strictly<br />

speaking, the extent <strong>of</strong> this pass through is dependent upon the price-responsiveness<br />

<strong>of</strong> demand for the packaging in question.<br />

In principle, this type <strong>of</strong> mechanism improves the efficiency <strong>of</strong> resource use, without<br />

necessarily being ‘efficient’ in the technical sense. The payments bear no relation to<br />

estimations <strong>of</strong> externalities associated with packaging waste management.<br />

Data for a number <strong>of</strong> years financing costs for Repak are shown in Table 12-6. These<br />

charges are effectively transferred onto producers, who account for the costs in the<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> their goods. The row highlighting ‘financing need’ is somewhat misleading<br />

since the payments are effectively set in advance, and do not bear relation to a<br />

funding gap required to deliver services. The figures do, however, indicate the<br />

average level <strong>of</strong> payments made per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste collected for recycling.<br />

Table 12-6: Cost-effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Compliance Scheme, Repak<br />

29/09/09<br />

2001 2001 2002 2002 2003 2003 2004<br />

2004<br />

Financing need*), mEUR 11.1 13.9 15.8 18.5<br />

Collected quantity, 1 000 t 237 323 415 470**)<br />

Financing need per t collected, EUR/t 47 43 38 39<br />

Change in financing need, per t collected, % – – 8 – 11 + 1<br />

*) Total turnover.<br />

**) Provisional Repak estimate, September 2004.<br />

Note: Note: The table covers response indicator 10 on cost-effectiveness. Data for 1997–1998 are not available. Data<br />

for 1999–2000 are not directly comparable with the ones in the table.<br />

Source: Source: Source: Repak communication for EEA Report


As noted above, there are differences in the cost <strong>of</strong> collecting packaging from<br />

households and from commerce and industry. As packaging recycling increases,<br />

proportionately more material is likely to be required to be captured from households.<br />

The EEA report notes: 247<br />

227<br />

“As increasing volumes <strong>of</strong> household waste, which are more expensive to<br />

collect than commercial waste, are collected as a result <strong>of</strong> the implementation<br />

<strong>of</strong> local authority waste management plans, it is anticipated that compliance<br />

costs will further increase in the years ahead.”<br />

Reflecting a similar perspective, in their National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2006 the EPA notes<br />

that with regard to packaging waste: 248<br />

“Packaging waste recycling is strong and continues to grow. Addressing the<br />

growth in the use <strong>of</strong> packaging, as illustrated by the growth in packaging<br />

waste, should now become a new priority for Repak, as opposed to finding<br />

new, and more expensive, sources <strong>of</strong> packaging waste to recycle”<br />

12.14 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Repak estimates that the number <strong>of</strong> Non Compliers, was about 1,050 in 2001,<br />

declining to an estimated 700 in 2004 and around 150 in 2008. It has been<br />

suggested that some <strong>of</strong> this can be attributed to stepped-up enforcement activity by<br />

the local authorities. According to Repak, 48 convictions have been secured by 8<br />

local authorities over a ten year period, with the maximum fine being €15,000. 249<br />

However, the record <strong>of</strong> enforcement does not appear to be an especially strong one. A<br />

clear issue for the scheme is that local authorities might not have sufficient<br />

resources, or incentives, to ensure compliance. In particular, if enforcement were to<br />

bring more companies within the compliance scheme fold, the levies required from<br />

each scheme member in order to provide revenue for RPS payments and other<br />

activities would decline. There is an argument, therefore, for removing the de minimis<br />

threshold altogether in the context <strong>of</strong> a tightened compliance regime. It might also be<br />

interesting for local authorities to be incentivised to enforce the scheme by, for<br />

example, designing this such that those who are not complying with the Regulations<br />

are required to pay fines to the local authorities themselves. This would require<br />

provision to be made for that purpose.<br />

12.15 Lessons Learned<br />

The Packaging Regulations have most likely had a positive effect in increasing the<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> packaging in Ireland through the application and use <strong>of</strong> various<br />

measures, including obligations on producers to segregate packaging waste and have<br />

247 EEA (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems in Selected Countries: An EEA<br />

Pilot Study, EEA Report No 03/2005.<br />

248 EPA (2007) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2006, Wexford: EPA.<br />

249 Information from Repak presentation to Eunomia, February 2009.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


it recycled, the requirement for companies to demonstrate obligations have been<br />

met, and the Repak scheme to reward collectors for collecting packaging waste. As<br />

far as we are aware, there has been no attempt to ‘apportion’ responsibility for the<br />

improvement to any one <strong>of</strong> the measures, let alone the Regulations themselves vis a<br />

vis other policy instruments. Several changes have been taking place simultaneously,<br />

so some <strong>of</strong> these will have contributed to progress made, notably, in our view, the<br />

increase in landfill gate fees, and the increasing buoyancy <strong>of</strong> markets for secondary<br />

materials in recent years.<br />

Although the legislation and efforts to date have been heavily focused on targets<br />

associated with recycling and recovery, it seems that there is a desire to shift<br />

emphasis in future towards packaging waste prevention. Initiatives thus far have<br />

centred around suasive measures, sometimes funded with public support. However,<br />

there would be merit in seeking to ensure that the RPS payments covered the whole<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> the provision <strong>of</strong> the collection service to households and businesses, this itself<br />

acting as an incentive to encourage additional effort in waste prevention on the part<br />

<strong>of</strong> producers.<br />

However, even with such a measure in place, there would be merit in – and the<br />

forgoing suggests that several stakeholders would support – measures to instate,<br />

within legislation, stronger requirements to take efforts to prevent waste. To the<br />

extent that this might stretch to consumers as well as producers, one means through<br />

which to achieve this could be efforts to provide those businesses who are not<br />

producers with the training and technical guidance to complete internal audits and<br />

assessments and identify areas within their businesses where packaging can be<br />

minimised. The approach to producers ought to be somewhat different, and should be<br />

considered as part <strong>of</strong> the obligation placed upon producers. Hence, whilst producers<br />

should be required to take actions to reduce, and prevent, packaging waste, public<br />

support should be targeted at those who are not producers, with assistance given to<br />

help minimise the generation <strong>of</strong> packaging waste. Furthermore, households could be<br />

encouraged, though changes in legislation, to report examples <strong>of</strong> excess packaging,<br />

which would trigger inspections <strong>of</strong> these cases against the technical arguments in<br />

support <strong>of</strong> the packaging approach used.<br />

228<br />

29/09/09


13.0 Producer Responsibility, Packaging -<br />

<strong>International</strong><br />

13.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

A generalised description <strong>of</strong> this policy would be that it makes the companies that<br />

bring packaging to the market responsible for its collection and recycling, though the<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> this responsibility varies from one country to another. All packaging,<br />

including retail packaging, such as plastic or paper bags and fast food wrappers can<br />

be included in the policy scope. Occasionally, the policy also aims explicitly to<br />

enhance both prevention and recycling <strong>of</strong> waste packaging.<br />

The companies who typically have some form <strong>of</strong> obligation under the policy may<br />

include those that:<br />

229<br />

� Package products;<br />

� Sell packaged products;<br />

� Import packaged products (including raw materials and parts);<br />

� Bring packaged products into the market under their brand name;<br />

� Provide customers with a carrier bag, other bag or box;<br />

� Produce carrier bags, other bags or boxes.<br />

Typically, a producer responsibility organisation will be established through which<br />

funds are directed from packaging producers to the organisations charged with<br />

recycling and recovery. The fee companies pay to the producer responsibility<br />

organisation is linked to the amount and type <strong>of</strong> packaging they introduce to the<br />

market and may also be linked to the costs <strong>of</strong> collecting, sorting and reprocessing the<br />

collected material, though this depends upon detailed implementation. The fee<br />

setting exercise is typically carried out annually and reflects the cost <strong>of</strong> the operation<br />

and takes into account the price received for the recyclates. In principle, the better<br />

quality and higher the market value <strong>of</strong> the recyclates, the cheaper the overall fee<br />

ought to become, reflecting the level <strong>of</strong> revenue generated by material sales.<br />

Another key factor influencing the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the levies paid, and the level <strong>of</strong><br />

achievement <strong>of</strong> the policy, is the level <strong>of</strong> the targets set as part <strong>of</strong> the policy.<br />

From a waste prevention perspective, there are three ways in which producer<br />

responsibility for packaging can aid prevention:<br />

� Reduce the volume and weight <strong>of</strong> packaging used (e.g. light weighting and<br />

reducing excessive packaging);<br />

� Increase the share <strong>of</strong> reusable packaging in the packaging market (e.g.<br />

refillable beverage cans); and<br />

� Reduce the toxicity <strong>of</strong> materials used in packaging (for example, heavy metals<br />

in glass).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


13.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

All EU Member States are forced to transpose the Producer Responsibility Directive(s)<br />

as specified in the European Union's Fifth Environment Action Programme. One <strong>of</strong> the<br />

key Directives is the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directive. 250 The method <strong>of</strong> transposition<br />

differs from country to country. Some <strong>of</strong> the more interesting (or most distinct)<br />

approaches are outlined below.<br />

In addition to EU Member States, several other countries, or states, have introduced<br />

producer responsibility policies on packaging, sometimes under the heading <strong>of</strong><br />

‘product stewardship’. The following is intended to give a flavour <strong>of</strong> the manner <strong>of</strong><br />

implementation.<br />

13.2.1 Germany<br />

The details <strong>of</strong> the German implementation are discussed in Section 14.0.<br />

13.2.2 Czech Republic<br />

The Czech Green Dot system for packaging started with a voluntary agreement in<br />

1999, which was supplemented by the obligation to recycle in 2001. In 2002, a<br />

Packaging Act defined more precisely the obligations connected with handling<br />

packaging and packaging waste. An increasing number <strong>of</strong> municipalities are now<br />

involved in the system.<br />

Producers <strong>of</strong> packaging pay a subscription to the Green Dot system, based on the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> packaging they produce. This is then used to help pay for the collection<br />

and recycling <strong>of</strong> packaging waste carried out by the municipalities and other<br />

authorised waste handlers. There is now a de minimis clause in the policy to exempt<br />

small producers.<br />

There are different license fees payable by material and by type <strong>of</strong> packaging i.e.<br />

whether it is consumer, trade, transport or industrial packaging.<br />

13.2.3 United Kingdom<br />

The Producer Responsibility Obligations (Packaging <strong>Waste</strong>) Regulations 2005 are the<br />

UK Government’s means <strong>of</strong> implementing the requirements <strong>of</strong> the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong><br />

250 Council Directive 94/62/EC on packaging and packaging waste (OJ No. L 365, 31.12.1994, p. 10)<br />

as amended by:<br />

230<br />

• Council Regulation (EC) No 1882/2003 adapting to Council Decision 1999/468/EC the<br />

provisions relating to committees which assist the Commission in the exercise <strong>of</strong> its<br />

implementing powers laid down in instruments subject to the procedure referred to in Article<br />

251 <strong>of</strong> the EC Treaty (OJ No. L 284, 31.10.2003, p. 1.);<br />

• Council Directive 2004/12/EC amending Directive 94/62/EC on packaging and packaging<br />

waste (OJ No. L 47, 18.2.2004, p. 26.); and<br />

• Council Directive 2005/20/EC amending Directive 94/62/EC on packaging and packaging<br />

waste (OJ No. L 70, 16.3.2005, p.17).<br />

29/09/09


Directive. The current Regulations are a consolidated version <strong>of</strong> the original<br />

regulations, which were amended a number <strong>of</strong> times. The regulations concentrate on<br />

important industrial and commercial sources (i.e. companies that handle more than<br />

50 tonnes <strong>of</strong> packaging per annum and have a turnover <strong>of</strong> more than £2 million per<br />

annum) and apply the shared producer responsibility approach.<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility policies currently in place in the UK.<br />

These are both legislative policies that have been transposed into UK law (as a<br />

means <strong>of</strong> implementing European Directives), and also voluntary measures,<br />

monitored by Government, that have been initiated by trade associations,<br />

manufacturers and retailers.<br />

In the UK, considerable time was spent seeking to understand who, in the supply<br />

chain, should hold what level <strong>of</strong> obligation <strong>of</strong> packaging placed on the market. The<br />

obligation which a given enterprise must meet is a function <strong>of</strong> the quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging it handles, with the proportion <strong>of</strong> this quantity being affected by its position<br />

in the supply chain:<br />

231<br />

� Raw Raw Raw material material material manufacturer: manufacturer: manufacturer: 6%. 6%.<br />

6%.<br />

Manufacturing <strong>of</strong> packaging raw materials. Example: Manufacturer <strong>of</strong> steel for<br />

baked beans cans.<br />

� Converter: Converter: 9%.<br />

9%.<br />

Manufacturing a recognised packaging item. Example: Manufacturer <strong>of</strong> the<br />

steel can for the baked beans.<br />

� Packer/filler: Packer/filler: 37%.<br />

37%.<br />

Putting a product into packaging or applying packaging to a product. Example:<br />

the Company which fills the can with baked beans.<br />

� Seller: Seller: Seller: 48%.<br />

48%.<br />

Supplying the packaging to the end user <strong>of</strong> that packaging. Example: The<br />

supermarket which sells the baked bean can to the consumer. Additionally it<br />

may be noted that a wholesaler selling cans <strong>of</strong> beans bulked up into boxes<br />

would have an obligation for the boxes which are removed by the supermarket.<br />

� Importer: Importer: rolled rolled rolled up up obligation.<br />

obligation.<br />

Companies who directly import packaging, packed goods or packaging<br />

material are also obligated. The level <strong>of</strong> their obligation depends on the stage<br />

<strong>of</strong> the chain at which the packaging is brought into the UK.<br />

Not all companies who handle packaging are obligated to recover and recycle<br />

packaging under the UK Regulation. ‘Producers’ are defined within the Regulation<br />

through Schedule 1. This sets thresholds for companies who are, or are not obligated<br />

to recover and recycled packaging under the Directive. These thresholds are set out in<br />

Para 3 <strong>of</strong> Schedule 1:<br />

3. A person satisfies the threshold tests if—<br />

a. his turnover in the last financial year in respect <strong>of</strong> which audited<br />

accounts are available before the relevant date was more than<br />

£2,000,000; and<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


232<br />

29/09/09<br />

b. in the calculation year the person handled in aggregate more than 50<br />

tonnes <strong>of</strong> packaging or packaging materials.<br />

Under the packaging waste regulations, a producer is obliged to recover and recycle<br />

the packaging that is needed to discharge its obligation either through its own<br />

actions, or through joining a compliance scheme. In the latter case, which is followed<br />

by the vast majority <strong>of</strong> obligated entities, the compliance scheme then takes on the<br />

producer’s obligation. There are currently 24 such compliance schemes in the UK.<br />

A de facto system <strong>of</strong> tradable compliance credits helps drive compliance forward. 251<br />

The nature <strong>of</strong> evidence which is generally used to demonstrate that the obligation <strong>of</strong> a<br />

company, or compliance scheme, has been discharged is the Packaging Recovery<br />

Note (and the Packaging Export Recovery Note). Accredited reprocessors are entitled<br />

to issue these when packaging waste is recycled or recovered, and they may sell<br />

them to obligated companies / compliance schemes. Essentially, if the market for<br />

‘evidence’, in the form or PRNs / PERNs is tight (demand is strong relative to supply),<br />

then the value <strong>of</strong> PRNs / PERNs will be higher than in situations where it is well<br />

known that compliance is assured. It should be noted that PRNs / PERNs are material<br />

specific, and since the relevant targets are also, the way in which PRN / PERN prices<br />

move reflects the market for evidence <strong>of</strong> compliance for specific materials. It also<br />

reflects what happens ‘at the margin’. In other words, if in a given year, compliance is<br />

certain to be secured, PRN/PERN values are very low. If, on the other hand, the<br />

market is tight, values increase, so that compliance costs are affected to a significant<br />

degree by what happens ‘at the margin’. Equally, the overall costs <strong>of</strong> PRNs and PERNs<br />

to producers and compliance schemes bear limited relation to the overall costs <strong>of</strong><br />

compliance, as represented by the costs <strong>of</strong> collecting, sorting and reprocessing<br />

packaging materials.<br />

13.2.4 Japan<br />

The Containers and Packaging Recycling Act (1995) introduced producer<br />

responsibility, at a time when 60% <strong>of</strong> household waste was deemed to be<br />

packaging. 252 The Japan Containers and Packaging Recycling Association (JCPRA)<br />

was set up to receive fees from producers and distributors <strong>of</strong> packaging and carry out<br />

the required recycling. It did not cover aluminium, steel or cardboard – these are<br />

recycled without any producer responsibility (the aluminium recycling rate was<br />

estimated at over 80% in 2000). 253 By being members and paying the appropriate<br />

fees, the producers and distributors undertake their recycling obligations.<br />

The JCPRA does not organise or operate the system for collection <strong>of</strong> the materials,<br />

this being carried out by the municipalities. The fees paid by members are a<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> the calculated recycling costs. These costs and proportions are agreed<br />

251 This scheme was not initially designed explicitly as a tradable credit scheme.<br />

252 Quoted from a 1995 survey by the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Health and Welfare, on the JCPA website,<br />

http://www.jcpra.or.jp/eng/jcpra/02.html<br />

253 Japan for Sustainability website, article <strong>of</strong> November 2004,<br />

http://www.japanfs.org/en/pages/025737.html


each year by an Industrial Structure Council, a body <strong>of</strong> industry representatives<br />

formed by the Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Economy, Trade and Industry, based on government<br />

waste forecasts.<br />

Recycling fees paid by the members are calculated as a proportion <strong>of</strong> the recycling<br />

unit cost and multiplied by their estimated output. 2009 recycling costs are shown in<br />

Table 13-1 below. The unit costs for PET, paper and plastics have fallen significantly<br />

since 2000. For example, the unit cost for PET bottles has come down from 88,000<br />

Yen per tonne in 2000 (€819 at January 2000 rates) to 1700 Yen per tonne (€14 at<br />

January 2009 rates) in 2009. 254<br />

Table 13-1: Japanese Recycling Unit Costs, 2009<br />

Glass<br />

233<br />

Material Material<br />

Cost Cost per per tonne tonne (Euro, (Euro, at at Jan Jan 2009 2009 exchange exchange exchange rate)<br />

rate)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Colourless 35<br />

Amber 47<br />

Other 78<br />

PET Bottles 14<br />

Paper 113<br />

Plastics 559<br />

Source: JCPRA, 2009<br />

The proportion <strong>of</strong> this recycling cost that members pay depends on their industrial<br />

sector, whether they are ‘users’ (companies that package their goods) or packaging<br />

manufacturers, and whether the packaging is classed as a container or wrapping (for<br />

paper and plastic).<br />

For example, a container user would pay 55% <strong>of</strong> the recycling cost <strong>of</strong> PET bottles per<br />

tonne used, while the manufacturer would pay around 5%. Proportions are as high as<br />

80% for users <strong>of</strong> plastic packaging (0.5% for manufacturers) and as low as 4% for<br />

users <strong>of</strong> paper packaging (0.3% for manufacturers).<br />

Japan historically has a high recycling rate for steel and aluminium because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

lack <strong>of</strong> space for landfill and the market value <strong>of</strong> the recyclates. PET rates are<br />

increasing fast with nearly 70% recycled (including municipal and other sources <strong>of</strong><br />

collection) in 2007, according to the Council for PET Bottle Recycling. 255 Plastic<br />

packaging recycling has increased from less than 60,000 tonnes in 2000 to over<br />

800,000 tonnes in 2007. Table 13-2 below shows the volume and change in<br />

packaging recycling in Japan. 256 It is also worth noting that, in Japan, some<br />

segregation schemes sort waste into ‘burnable’ and ‘non-burnable’ fractions, with<br />

plastics considered non-burnable.<br />

254 From the JCPRA website, accessed January 2009, http://www.jcpra.or.jp/eng/statistics.html<br />

255 PET Council for Recycling website accessed January 2009, http://www.petbottlerec.gr.jp/english/index.html<br />

256 From the JCPRA website, accessed January 2009, http://www.jcpra.or.jp/eng/statistics.html


Table 13-2: Packaging Recycling in Japan<br />

Glass<br />

234<br />

29/09/09<br />

Material Material<br />

Volume Volume recycled recycled 2007<br />

2007<br />

% % change change in in recycling<br />

recycling<br />

2000 2000-2007 2000 2007<br />

Colourless 131,666 -29<br />

Amber 107,754 16<br />

Other 112,495 15<br />

PET Bottles 272,850 182<br />

Paper 56,364 18<br />

Plastics 802,036 429<br />

Source: JCPRA, accessed January 2009<br />

13.2.5 Other countries<br />

Producer responsibility schemes for packaging have also been introduced in Korea,<br />

Canada, Taiwan, Brazil, Argentina and Mexico.<br />

13.2.6 Commercial and Industrial Packaging Collection and Recycling<br />

It is interesting to note the different ways in which countries split responsibilities for<br />

dealing with packaging waste from households, and packaging waste from<br />

commercial and industrial sources. In some countries, there are different<br />

organisations dealing with commercial and industrial packaging, and household<br />

packaging (DSD in Germany, for example, only collects household packaging), whilst<br />

in other countries, the same organisation does both jobs (Conai in Italy, for example).<br />

There is little information about the split between household and non-household<br />

packaging in Europe apart from the assumed split used in the <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy for<br />

England 2007, shown in Table 13-3. If these figures are representative <strong>of</strong> other<br />

countries, then it seems reasonable to state that given that around half <strong>of</strong> non-wood<br />

packaging (and 44% <strong>of</strong> all packaging) is derived from households, those countries<br />

that target both the household packaging stream and the commercial stream are<br />

likely to be at the top <strong>of</strong> the overall packaging recycling table.<br />

Table 13-3: UK Split <strong>of</strong> Household/non-Household Packaging, 2004<br />

Material Household C&I<br />

Total tonnage (‘000) Tonnes (‘000) % Tonnes (‘000) %<br />

Paper 3,725 931 25% 2,794 75%<br />

Glass 2,400 1,800 75% 600 25%<br />

Aluminium 141 134 95% 7 5%<br />

Steel 690 483 70% 207 30%<br />

Plastics 1,844 1,176 64% 668 36%<br />

Sub-total excluding wood 8,800 4,524 51% 4,276 49%<br />

Wood 1,404 0 0% 1,404 100%<br />

Other 22 0 22<br />

Total packaging 10,226 4,524 44% 5,702 56%<br />

Table 13-4 below shows the European situation for household/non-household<br />

producer responsibility organisations. Commercial and industrial packaging is


generally cheaper to collect as it arises in larger quantities, and is <strong>of</strong>ten more<br />

homogeneous (potentially increasing the sales value <strong>of</strong> the material). In schemes<br />

where targets are set at less ambitious levels, then particularly where there is no<br />

distinct separation <strong>of</strong> responsibilities, commercial and industrial packaging tends to<br />

be collected first (as ‘low hanging fruit’).<br />

Table 13-4: Producer Responsibility Organisations<br />

235<br />

Country<br />

Country<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Organisation Organisation for for Household Household<br />

Household<br />

Packaging<br />

Packaging<br />

Organisation Organisation for<br />

for<br />

Commercial/Industrial<br />

Commercial/Industrial<br />

Packaging<br />

Packaging<br />

Austria Branch organisations Branch organisations<br />

Belgium Fost Plus Val-I-Pack<br />

Finland PYR PYR<br />

France ECO-Emballages, Adelphe<br />

No organisation exists – it is up<br />

to each company producing C&I<br />

packaging to be responsible for<br />

its recycling<br />

Germany DSD Different organisations<br />

Ireland Repak Repak<br />

Italy Conai Conai<br />

Luxembourg Valorlux<br />

Portugal SPV SPV<br />

Spain Ecoembalajes, Ecovidrio<br />

Sweden REPA<br />

Valorlux for commercial, no<br />

organisation for industrial<br />

(industrial companies must<br />

satisfy regulations themselves)<br />

No organisation exists – it is up<br />

to the companies and<br />

municipalities<br />

For most companies, no<br />

organisation: waste<br />

management companies handle<br />

packaging. For small<br />

companies, REPA provide free<br />

collection points<br />

UK Split between household & commercial/industrial is not applicable<br />

13.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Packaging Recovery Organisation (PRO) Europe is an international umbrella<br />

organisation for national member systems for the recovery and recycling <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

waste in Europe. All these systems use the Green Dot mark as a symbol <strong>of</strong> financing<br />

packaging waste recycling. The PRO has the following remit:


236<br />

� It serves as a forum for the participating national partner organisations, as an<br />

intensive exchange <strong>of</strong> experiences and ideas essential for optimal application<br />

<strong>of</strong> Directive ES 94/62 on packaging and packaging waste;<br />

� It grants the right to use the Green Dot registered trademark in accordance<br />

with certain rules applied to individual systems which are established in<br />

participating European states, the objective <strong>of</strong> which is the optimal application<br />

<strong>of</strong> Directive ES 94/62;<br />

� It develops and checks the criteria for using the Green Dot trademark for<br />

manufacturers and distributors <strong>of</strong> packaging and/or packaged goods in<br />

accordance with the European Cartel Office.<br />

In each country there is an authorised licensee <strong>of</strong> Green Dot. For example, in<br />

Germany the licensee is Duales System Deutschland GmbH, while in the Czech<br />

Republic, it is EKO-KOM a.s.<br />

Countries where Green Dot is not in operation, such as Japan, have an equivalent<br />

organisation (in that case, the JCPRA), which receives fees and either organises the<br />

collection and recycling, or contributes financially towards it.<br />

13.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The following sources <strong>of</strong> information, as well as other sources, are the basis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

overview that follows:<br />

Schwarz and Gattuso (2002) Extended Producer Responsibility: Reexamining Its Role<br />

in Environmental Progress, Report for the Reason Foundation,<br />

www.reason.org/ps293.pdf<br />

European European Union<br />

Union<br />

Report from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, 2006 The<br />

Implementation Of Directive 94/62/Ec On Packaging And Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> And Its<br />

Impact On The Environment, As Well As On The Functioning Of The Internal Market,<br />

Dec 2006.<br />

Report from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, 2005<br />

Taking sustainable use <strong>of</strong> resources forward: A Thematic Strategy on the prevention<br />

and recycling <strong>of</strong> waste, Dec 2005<br />

Perchards (2005) Study On The Progress Of The Implementation And Impact Of<br />

Directive 94/62/Ec On The Functioning Of The Internal Market, Final Report to the<br />

Europen Commission, May 2005<br />

Argus (2001) European Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems, Report for the<br />

European Commission, February 2001<br />

European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging waste management systems in selected countries: an EEA pilot study,<br />

Report for the European Environment Agency, 2005.<br />

Taylor Nelson S<strong>of</strong>res (2000) Cost-Efficiency Of Packaging Recovery Systems- the<br />

Case Of France, Germany, The Netherlands And The United Kingdom, Report for the<br />

European Commission, February 2000.<br />

29/09/09


Netherlands<br />

Netherlands<br />

Netherlands<br />

Henderson (1997) <strong>Waste</strong> charges and taxes in the Netherlands , pp. 97-112, in<br />

Environmental taxes and charges, Dublin: European Foundation.<br />

Ger Germany Ger many<br />

Prognos AG (2002) Assessment <strong>of</strong> Sustainability and the Perspectives <strong>of</strong> the DSD,<br />

report commissioned by the Duales System Deutschland AG, Düsseldorf, June 2002.<br />

Öko-Institut (2002) Advantage <strong>of</strong> the Green Dot for the Environment, report<br />

commissioned by the Duales System Deutschland AG, Düsseldorf, March 2002.<br />

United United Kingdom<br />

Kingdom<br />

David Davies Associates (2005) Packflow 2008 , UK compliance with the 2008<br />

targets <strong>of</strong> the European Packaging & Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directive,<br />

http://www.valpak.co.uk/docs/packaging/packflow_2008_summary_report_recomm<br />

endations.pdf<br />

Perchards (2003) Impacts <strong>of</strong> the Packaging (Essential Requirements) Regulations: A<br />

Brief Survey, Report for DTI, Oct 2003.<br />

13.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

13.5.1 Across Europe<br />

Packaging consumption is responsible for around 80 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> CO2 equivalent<br />

per annum in the EU 15 (2% <strong>of</strong> the total emissions). The recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging has been attributed with greenhouse gas savings and also reduces other<br />

environmental impacts, such as those associated with residual waste treatments,<br />

whilst it also reduces emissions <strong>of</strong> particulates and other air pollutants, and soil<br />

acidification.<br />

Table 13-5 shows recycling and recovery rates for all packaging in the EU 15 for 2001<br />

and 2006, with countries ordered by 2006 recycling performance. This is shown<br />

graphically in Figure 13-1. Table 13-6 shows the split <strong>of</strong> financial responsibility for the<br />

collection and sorting <strong>of</strong> household packaging, according to Perchards, and with<br />

updates where available. 257 This is significant as it is one <strong>of</strong> the two main financial<br />

variables seen in the implementation in Europe that may have an impact on the<br />

recycling rate. Where producer responsibility schemes fund the same range <strong>of</strong><br />

services (e.g. in Germany, Belgium and Austria, where 100% <strong>of</strong> the collection and<br />

sorting <strong>of</strong> household waste is funded), the other financial variable between them is<br />

the fee for each type <strong>of</strong> packaging material – see Table 13-7 under implementation<br />

costs for a cross section <strong>of</strong> these.<br />

Table 13-6 shows that the top three countries in terms <strong>of</strong> recycling all packaging each<br />

visits 100% <strong>of</strong> the financial burden <strong>of</strong> collection and sorting household packaging<br />

257 Perchards (2005) Study On The Progress Of The Implementation And Impact Of Directive 94/62/Ec<br />

On The Functioning Of The Internal Market, Final Report to the Europen Commission, May 2005.<br />

237<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


materials onto the packaging industry, rather than the household / municipality. They<br />

all have more or less universal household waste collections for packaging, and thus<br />

would be expected to have some <strong>of</strong> the higher fees in Europe. Some cases suggest a<br />

gradual move towards a higher percentage: for example, Italy’s producer<br />

responsibility organisation was estimated to cover 65% <strong>of</strong> costs in 2001, but now<br />

covers around 83% (with the intention being to have 100% cost coverage).<br />

Table 13-5: Packaging Recycling Rates (all packaging)<br />

238<br />

29/09/09<br />

Country Country Country 2001 2001 % % Recycling Recycling Recycling 2001 2001 % % Recovery Recovery 2006 2006 % % Recycling Recycling Recycling 2006 2006 % % Recovery<br />

Recovery<br />

Belgium 71 88 79 94.5<br />

Austria 64 73 68 87.5<br />

Germany 76 79 66.5 88<br />

Luxembourg 57 69 64 92.5<br />

Netherlands 56 59 60 88<br />

Sweden 63 66 58 81<br />

UK 42 48 57.5 62<br />

Denmark 57 90 56 94<br />

Portugal 38 52 56 56<br />

Italy 46 51 55 65<br />

France 44 59 55 64<br />

Ireland 27 27 54.5 57<br />

Spain 44 50 54 61<br />

Finland 47 62 49 77<br />

Greece 33 33 43 43<br />

Source: European Commission, accessed 2009<br />

Many <strong>of</strong> the European countries’ producer responsibility organisations work with the<br />

municipalities to some degree to organise collection and sorting <strong>of</strong> waste packaging.<br />

The UK solution is different as accredited reprocessors <strong>of</strong> recyclates sell packaging<br />

recovery notes (PRNs) for each tonne <strong>of</strong> material they process into what amounts to a<br />

market for compliance credits, some <strong>of</strong> which are openly traded. Companies that put<br />

packaging on the market (or the compliance scheme <strong>of</strong> which they choose to be a<br />

member) then buy these PRNs to the tonnage value <strong>of</strong> that packaging. This process<br />

supports the market for reprocessing; it has no direct link with the collection and<br />

sorting <strong>of</strong> packaging waste (household or non-household). It therefore does not fund<br />

the collection <strong>of</strong> recyclable materials directly, but it may influence the price <strong>of</strong><br />

materials <strong>of</strong>fered by reprocessors at any moment in time (though this is likely to be<br />

incremental for local authorities operating services through contracts with operators).


Figure 13-1: Packaging Recycling and Recovery Rates in the EU15 (all packaging)<br />

239<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Belgium<br />

Austria<br />

Germany<br />

Luxemburg<br />

Netherlands<br />

Sweden<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

UK<br />

Denmark<br />

Portugal<br />

Italy<br />

France<br />

Ireland<br />

Spain<br />

Finland<br />

Greece<br />

2001 % Recycling<br />

2001 % Recovery<br />

2006 % Recycling<br />

2006 % Recovery


Table 13-6: Split <strong>of</strong> the Financial Burden <strong>of</strong> Collection and Sorting <strong>of</strong> Household<br />

Packaging<br />

Country<br />

Country<br />

240<br />

29/09/09<br />

% % <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

collection/sorting<br />

collection/sorting<br />

collection/sorting<br />

cost cost borne borne by<br />

by<br />

recovery<br />

recovery<br />

organisation<br />

organisation<br />

% % <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

collection/sorting<br />

collection/sorting<br />

cost cost borne borne borne by<br />

by<br />

municipality municipality /<br />

/<br />

households households<br />

households<br />

Belgium 100 0<br />

Austria 100 0<br />

Germany 100 0<br />

Luxembourg unclear unclear<br />

Netherlands<br />

Reported as 1% (in<br />

2001) by<br />

Perchards (2005)<br />

Reported as 99%<br />

(in 2001) by<br />

Perchards<br />

(2005)<br />

Sweden 95 5<br />

UK<br />

Reported as 7% (in<br />

2001) by<br />

Perchards (2005)<br />

Reported as 93%<br />

(in 2001) by<br />

Perchards<br />

(2005)<br />

Denmark 2 98<br />

Portugal 65 35<br />

Comment<br />

Comment<br />

Fost Plus organises and finances collection <strong>of</strong><br />

glass (bring site); paper and card; plastic<br />

bottles and flasks, metallic packaging and<br />

drink cartons<br />

ARA runs nationwide systems for the<br />

collection and recovery <strong>of</strong> all household and<br />

commercial packaging waste<br />

Duales System Deutschland GmbH organises<br />

the collection, sorting and recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging waste in Germany with the support<br />

<strong>of</strong> 724 waste management partners<br />

Designed to cover all expenses <strong>of</strong> collecting,<br />

sorting and recycling packaging. Valorlux<br />

transfer funds per tonne to the municipalities<br />

based on tonnages handed over to registered<br />

recycling plants: Glass €36.92; Paper €6.68;<br />

Cardboard €18.56; other (plastic & metal)<br />

€164.52<br />

The traditional approach has been to increase<br />

packaging recycling through a voluntary<br />

agreement between government and local<br />

authorities. Since January 2008, a packaging<br />

tax is payable, with some <strong>of</strong> the revenue going<br />

to a waste fund which pays out to<br />

municipalities per kg collected<br />

The producer responsibility organisation,<br />

REPA owns the national bring system, around<br />

5,800 places. It contracts waste management<br />

companies for transportation and recycling.<br />

PRNs provide support for recycling market<br />

rather than direct support to municipalities.<br />

Perchards’ percentages likely to be out <strong>of</strong><br />

date, but no new estimate available<br />

No producer responsibility – instead a<br />

packaging tax covers the cost <strong>of</strong> municipal<br />

responsibility for recycling/recovery. Also, a<br />

deposit refund scheme is in place


Country<br />

Country<br />

241<br />

% % <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

collection/sorting<br />

collection/sorting<br />

cost cost borne borne by<br />

by<br />

recovery recovery<br />

recovery<br />

organisation<br />

organisation<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

% % % <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

collection/sorting<br />

collection/sorting<br />

cost cost borne borne borne by<br />

by<br />

municipality municipality /<br />

/<br />

households households<br />

households<br />

Italy 83 17<br />

Comment<br />

Comment<br />

The principle is that 100% <strong>of</strong> costs are<br />

covered by the PRO, but the estimated<br />

position is 83% 258<br />

France 65 35 Still an accurate assessment in 2009 259<br />

Ireland 68 - 92 8 - 32<br />

Spain 65 35<br />

Finland 7 93<br />

Greece 0 100<br />

Source: Perchards (2005), and updates based on personal communications<br />

Repak estimates – Repak paid an average<br />

domestic subsidy <strong>of</strong> €77 per tonne in 2008<br />

and estimate that the direct cost base is in<br />

the region <strong>of</strong> €84 to €113 (before receipt <strong>of</strong><br />

income from sale <strong>of</strong> recyclates) 260<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> waste prevention, the picture for all packaging, in Figure 13-2, is not<br />

particularly clear. It is likely that this is somewhat affected by differing perceptions<br />

regarding reporting requirements as well as different methodologies for reporting <strong>of</strong><br />

data. Whilst Belgium, Austria and Sweden have a smaller waste generation per capita<br />

than the EU15 average, Germany and Luxembourg do not (despite the high charges<br />

per tonne <strong>of</strong> packaging in Germany). 261 However, other reports (see section 13.5.2<br />

below), suggest that in an earlier period (from 1991 to 2000), there was a waste<br />

prevention impact. The packaging waste generation per capita also reflects the<br />

wealth and consumption habits <strong>of</strong> the country. Unfortunately the household/nonhousehold<br />

split <strong>of</strong> packaging waste was not obtainable for all countries, but this<br />

would certainly help shed additional light on the situation. Another complicating factor<br />

might be the presence <strong>of</strong> re-use targets and deposit refund schemes in some<br />

countries.<br />

What is interesting is that by some measures, the Irish system does not appear to<br />

perform especially well, on a comparative basis. For example, in terms <strong>of</strong> what might<br />

be an appropriate target for packaging, the recycling target is a useful driver but it<br />

does not incentivise waste prevention. It could be that a more suitable target, which<br />

would reward waste prevention, would be a target to ensure residual waste packaging<br />

is below a specified level. For the old EU-15, this is shown in Figure 13-3.<br />

258 Personal communication with Enzo Favoino <strong>of</strong> the Scuola Agraria del Parco di Monza, June 2009.<br />

259 Personal communication with Pascal Gislais, June 2009.<br />

260 Personal communication with Tony O’Sullivan, Repak, June 2009.<br />

261 European Environment Agency website, accessed January 2009,<br />

http://dataservice.eea.europa.eu/atlas/viewdata/viewpub.asp?id=2696


Figure 13-2: Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Generation (kg per capita)<br />

242<br />

29/09/09<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Hungary<br />

Greece<br />

Poland<br />

Slovenia<br />

Estonia<br />

Finland<br />

Latvia<br />

Austria<br />

Sweden<br />

Belgium<br />

Portugal<br />

EU 27<br />

United Kingdom<br />

Denmark<br />

Spain<br />

EU15<br />

Germany<br />

France<br />

Italy<br />

Netherlands<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Ireland<br />

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006<br />

Source: European Environment Agency, accessed January 2009<br />

Figure 13-3: Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> per Capita, and Unrecycled / Unrecovered Quantities<br />

Packaging (kg per capita)<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

IRE<br />

M<br />

IT<br />

F<br />

SP<br />

LUX<br />

P<br />

DK<br />

UK<br />

SWE<br />

FI<br />

GER<br />

CY<br />

EST<br />

SLO<br />

POL<br />

GR<br />

LIT<br />

Total Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> (kg per capita) Unrecycled Packaging (kg per capita)<br />

H<br />

A<br />

ROM<br />

BU<br />

SLA<br />

BE<br />

CZ<br />

NO<br />

Sources: Packaging quantities, recycling and recovery rates for 2006 from European Commission:<br />

http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/waste/data/packaging_waste Population data<br />

from Eurostat.<br />

http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/tgm/table.do?tab=table&language=en&pcode=tps00001&tableSel<br />

ection=1&footnotes=yes&labeling=labels&plugin=1


It can be seen that against this measure, the Irish position is one with very high per<br />

capita generation, and reflecting this, given that many other countries have decent<br />

recycling performance, the performance in respect <strong>of</strong> residual waste is not especially<br />

good. Having said that, the quality <strong>of</strong> the data is not what it might be, and the<br />

calculation in respect <strong>of</strong> per capita quantities might not be especially robust. The<br />

figure also suggests that this type <strong>of</strong> target would be much fairer across the EU as a<br />

whole, with countries at lower income levels effectively performing better than those<br />

at higher income levels, even at relatively low recycling levels.<br />

13.5.2 Packaging Regulations Essential Requirements<br />

Three countries – the UK, France and the Czech Republic - have put enforcement<br />

measures in place to enforce compliance with the Essential Requirements for<br />

packaging (Articles 9, 10 and 11 <strong>of</strong> the Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directive). These include<br />

minimisation <strong>of</strong> packaging weight and volume to the amount needed for safety and<br />

consumer acceptance <strong>of</strong> the packed product, and suitability for reuse, material<br />

recycling, energy recovery or composting. Packaging materials must also keep the<br />

concentration <strong>of</strong> heavy metals below certain targets.<br />

The UK and France both use the CEN (European Committee for Standardisation)<br />

standards as a baseline for packaging. PIRA and Ecolas in 2004 identified a<br />

correlation between enforcement <strong>of</strong> the Essential Requirements in France and the UK<br />

and a decoupling <strong>of</strong> GDP from packaging waste generation. This decoupling is<br />

comparable with that in Belgium and Spain, where the requirement to develop<br />

prevention plans appears to have had broadly similar effects, and is greater than for<br />

EU-15 as a whole. 262 The CEN standard on prevention by source reduction (EN<br />

13428: 2000) provides companies with a methodology for a systematic evaluation <strong>of</strong><br />

their packaging reduction opportunities.<br />

13.6 Implementation Costs<br />

The implementation costs <strong>of</strong> the producer responsibility will depend upon a range <strong>of</strong><br />

factors in a given country, amongst other being:<br />

243<br />

• The baseline waste management system (what was happening before the<br />

system was introduced);<br />

• What are the background costs <strong>of</strong> residual waste collection and treatment;<br />

• How the market for waste collection is configured;<br />

• Whether or not countries operate pay-by-use schemes;<br />

• The quality <strong>of</strong> the material being collected for recycling; and<br />

• The possibilities for marketing materials in a pro-active manner;<br />

262 Study On The Progress Of The Implementation And Impact Of Directive 94/62/Ec On The<br />

Functioning Of The Internal Market, Perchards, 2005<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


What is <strong>of</strong>ten reported in the literature is the cost <strong>of</strong> the producer responsibility<br />

scheme, sometimes referred to as the ‘financing need’, but the reality is that the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> collection, sorting and reprocessing have to be shouldered by somebody, and<br />

the manner <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility, whilst it may affect the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> implementation, probably has the most significant effect on the distribution<br />

<strong>of</strong> these costs across households / local authorities / businesses (those who pay for<br />

the collection <strong>of</strong> waste) and the obligated companies (those whose responsibility it is<br />

to demonstrate compliance). In essence, whatever the costs <strong>of</strong> the system, those<br />

which are not borne by ‘producers’ will have to be borne by other actors.<br />

The key financial actors are the waste collector and the producer responsibility<br />

organisation (representing the packaging manufacturers and ‘users’). In the German<br />

example, the waste collection is wholly paid for by the producer responsibility<br />

organisation (based on the fees charged to the manufacturers and users). The DSD’s<br />

18,560 members paid 540 million Euros (£377.6 million) in 2003. With DSD<br />

receiving Green Dot fees for 4,495,692 tonnes <strong>of</strong> packaging waste, this makes for an<br />

average <strong>of</strong> over €120 per tonne. This figure includes the income from recycled<br />

material. Costs (licence fees) payable to DSD for packaging produced or sold in<br />

Germany are shown in Figure 13-4.<br />

In schemes such as the Japanese one, the collection is done at a cost to the<br />

municipality and a share <strong>of</strong> the recycling cost is borne by the producer responsibility<br />

organisation (to bridge the gap between the cost <strong>of</strong> the recycling process and the<br />

value <strong>of</strong> the recyclate).<br />

In schemes such as that operated in the UK, the vast majority <strong>of</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

household collection is borne by taxpayers, whilst obligated companies contribute a<br />

fraction <strong>of</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong> collecting, sorting and reprocessing the material. The<br />

Table 13-7 shows the fees levied by material in some <strong>of</strong> the Green Dot schemes in<br />

Europe, all expressed in Euros per tonne. Where the producer responsibility scheme<br />

pays 100% <strong>of</strong> the collection and sorting <strong>of</strong> household waste there are generally higher<br />

fees to pay for these efforts. In addition, one notes that the fees tend to follow the<br />

relative costs <strong>of</strong> collection. Plastics, being a low bulk density material, and typically<br />

requiring post-collection sorting, are relatively more expensive to collect, even taking<br />

into account the relatively high revenues which can be obtained from sales <strong>of</strong> sorted<br />

polymers. In all countries shown, the fees for plastic are high, whereas the fees for<br />

glass are much lower, reflecting the lower costs, and in many parts <strong>of</strong> Europe, the<br />

reduced necessity for colour sorting and / or the potential to collect high proportions<br />

<strong>of</strong> glass through bring schemes.<br />

244<br />

29/09/09


Figure 13-4: German License Fees Payable to the Governing Authority per Tonne <strong>of</strong><br />

Packaging Produced (effective 2007)<br />

Licence fee per tonne (euro)<br />

245<br />

1400<br />

1200<br />

1000<br />

800<br />

600<br />

400<br />

200<br />

0<br />

Plastic Other composites Beverage cartons Aluminium Tin-plate Paper and<br />

cardboard<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Material<br />

Natural materials Glass<br />

Table 13-7: Fees by Material for Green Dot schemes in Europe (Euros per tonne)<br />

Material<br />

Material<br />

Belgium<br />

Belgium<br />

(2008)<br />

(2008)<br />

Germany<br />

Germany<br />

(2007) (2007)<br />

(2007)<br />

Austria<br />

Austria<br />

(2007)<br />

(2007)<br />

France<br />

France<br />

(2007)<br />

(2007)<br />

Spain<br />

Spain<br />

(2008)<br />

(2008)<br />

Greece Greece<br />

Greece<br />

(2005) (2005) (2005) *<br />

Glass 29.30 74 61 3.6 - 10<br />

Plastics 159.40 1296 610 177.80 278-329 62<br />

Steel 18.80 - - 22.60 61 20<br />

Aluminium 33.90 733 370 45.30 102 8<br />

Paper/card 15.70 175 105 122.10 51 50<br />

*Plus a fee <strong>of</strong> 0.4 Euro cents per item<br />

Source: Pro Europe, 2008<br />

This can be contrasted with the UK scheme where the fluctuation in PRN price is<br />

driven by the closeness to balance <strong>of</strong> supply and demand for PRNs as ‘evidence’. The<br />

fluctuating value <strong>of</strong> PRNs is shown in Figure 13-5. This shows, for example, how for<br />

most materials, following the end <strong>of</strong> the 2001 compliance year, PRN prices for most<br />

materials made no upward movement in the period to the end <strong>of</strong> 2003 as<br />

Government did not change the level <strong>of</strong> the targets from 2001 to 2003 (and everyone<br />

knew they would be met).<br />

In 2004, material specific rates were introduced, and the overall recovery<br />

requirement was much more closely aligned with the recycling requirement. This<br />

meant that energy recovery PRNs lost a considerable amount <strong>of</strong> their value, although<br />

those for recovery <strong>of</strong> energy from wood have remained somewhat higher. What


appears to be happening, however, is that as targets rise, the PRN values for some<br />

materials are becoming more volatile and it would appear, at least from the price<br />

trends, that there has been greater anxiety surrounding targets for the metals, for<br />

plastic and for glass than for other materials. On the other hand, the sensitivity <strong>of</strong> the<br />

market to changes in information and data is also clear. Announcements by Defra<br />

that the quantity <strong>of</strong> obligated packaging placed on the market was 466,000 tonnes<br />

(5%) or so less than was previously estimated for 2006 sent PRN prices tumbling<br />

downwards.<br />

Figure 13-5: Evolution in PRN Values for Specific Materials<br />

PRN Price (£/tonne material)<br />

246<br />

180<br />

160<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

Oct-00<br />

Jan-01<br />

Apr-01<br />

Jul-01<br />

Oct-01<br />

Jan-02<br />

Apr-02<br />

Jul-02<br />

Oct-02<br />

Jan-03<br />

Apr-03<br />

Jul-03<br />

Month / Year<br />

Oct-03<br />

Jan-04<br />

Apr-04<br />

Jul-04<br />

Oct-04<br />

Jan-05<br />

Apr-05<br />

Jul-05<br />

Oct-05<br />

Jan-06<br />

Apr-06<br />

Jul-06<br />

Oct-06<br />

Glass<br />

Paper<br />

Aluminium<br />

Steel<br />

Plastics<br />

Mixed - energy recovery<br />

Wood - energy recovery<br />

This is not an effective mechanism to support local authority investment in recycling,<br />

not that <strong>of</strong> industry, and tends not to incentivize ongoing efforts to prevent packaging<br />

waste, nor to design it for recyclability. It also bears no relation to the ongoing costs <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling activity. PRN revenues were £59 million and £57 million per annum in 2006<br />

and 2007, respectively. A broad brush estimate <strong>of</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong> only household services<br />

for packaging waste recycling in the UK would be <strong>of</strong> the order £200-£250 million,<br />

suggesting that the funding within the system covers at the very most around a<br />

quarter <strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> household waste recycling, but most likely, a rather smaller<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> recycling household and non-household packaging.<br />

13.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Generally, producer responsibility for packaging increases recycling <strong>of</strong> packaging,<br />

though it <strong>of</strong>ten is one <strong>of</strong> a range <strong>of</strong> policies used to achieve this objective. The<br />

incentive imparted to companies to minimise waste varies with the extent to which<br />

they are made financially responsible for the system being implemented.<br />

It can be expected that material switching will take place at the margin either to avoid<br />

the heavier materials, or to avoid the more difficult to recycle packaging materials.


This is likely to have been dependent upon the weight based payments made by<br />

obligated entities, and the targets the scheme is required to meet. Some materials<br />

are lower in weight, but some <strong>of</strong> these, notably plastics, are more expensive to<br />

recycle.<br />

Reuse systems that had been based on glass (such as in Denmark and Finland) have<br />

been encouraged through tax policy to remain reuse rather than one-way, but start to<br />

move to PET bottles. This was the case after the Finnish tax was introduced in 1994,<br />

as shown in Table 13-8. Where legislative support has not been in place for reusable<br />

systems, these have tended to dramatically diminish.<br />

Table 13-8: Finnish Packaging Mix<br />

247<br />

1995 1995 Market Market Share Share %<br />

%<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

1999 1999 Estimated Estimated<br />

Estimated<br />

Market Market Market Share Share % %<br />

%<br />

1995 1995-9 1995 9 Growth Growth Growth %<br />

%<br />

Cans 13 16 25<br />

Refillable Glass 77 64 -18<br />

Non-refillable Glass 0 0 0<br />

Refillable PET/PEN 9 19 97<br />

Non-refillable PET/PEN 0 0 0<br />

Total 100 100 -2<br />

Source: Study on Environmental Taxes and Charges in the EU, 2001<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> drivers for technical innovation in packaging and so it is not<br />

always simple to assign change to a particular one. For example, lightweighting <strong>of</strong><br />

aluminium cans would be driven by the price <strong>of</strong> the material, so the producer<br />

responsibility fee would have to be high in order to contribute more inducement.<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the recent packaging changes do however point towards single material use,<br />

such as the all cardboard packaging for Duracell batteries or some small electrical<br />

appliances. In addition, the increase in use <strong>of</strong> re-usable packaging – particularly for<br />

haulage <strong>of</strong> products in crates / pallets has been incentivised by producer<br />

responsibility.<br />

13.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The cost <strong>of</strong> packaging waste collection and disposal is covered either by municipal<br />

charges or by a producer responsibility organisation. See Table 13-6 for the split in<br />

Europe. Where the majority <strong>of</strong> the cost is covered by the producer responsibility<br />

organisation, it is recouped via the producers from the cost <strong>of</strong> their products.<br />

Otherwise, it is charged directly to the householders either as a flat charge or a<br />

mixture <strong>of</strong> fixed and variable (by use) charges.<br />

13.9 Complementary Policies<br />

In a number <strong>of</strong> countries deposit refund systems are used in conjunction with<br />

producer responsibility. They are an attempt to increase recycling rates and address<br />

the problem <strong>of</strong> littering by giving an incentive to the consumer to take back the<br />

container. A one-way container tax is complementary to producer responsibility,


incentivising producers to set up reuse systems. There is not yet unequivocal<br />

evidence to support this – reuse systems depend on short delivery distances and<br />

repeated reuse to score environmentally over on-way packaging. Allied to this,<br />

policies to encourage a minimum recycled content, such as that in Belgium, in which<br />

containers that are made with more than 50% recycled material are exempted from<br />

the one-way container tax may help to support the recyclate market.<br />

As referred to in the introduction, the other policy to complement producer<br />

responsibility is PBU. Producer responsibility can favour one material type over<br />

another, which PBU cannot. PBU can adjust the marginal cost per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management by location, reflecting the differing costs associated with urban or rural<br />

areas.<br />

Other policies which support producer responsibility are policies which make the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> dealing with residual waste relatively high (landfill / incineration levies and<br />

bans). In these cases, irrespective <strong>of</strong> the distribution <strong>of</strong> costs, there will be incentives<br />

to increase recycling and to prevent waste so as to avoid the high costs <strong>of</strong> residual<br />

waste treatment / disposal.<br />

13.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> incremental costs <strong>of</strong> the producer responsibility policy:<br />

248<br />

� Capital equipment (for reuse);<br />

� Storage space (for reuse);<br />

� Information gathering and reporting;<br />

� ‘Marketing’ <strong>of</strong> the service;<br />

� Establishment <strong>of</strong> the institutions;<br />

� Administration overheads; and<br />

� Operation <strong>of</strong> the recycling/recovery (covered by fees).<br />

The cost <strong>of</strong> the policy applied to household packaging can be borne either by the<br />

taxpayer, supporting the work <strong>of</strong> the municipalities, or the packers/fillers/importers,<br />

or shared between the two. If the cost is partially or totally borne by industry, then<br />

depending on the elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand for the product and the commercial conditions,<br />

some or all <strong>of</strong> the cost may be passed onto the end consumer. This can be<br />

considered as another cost <strong>of</strong> production, and the producers<br />

(packers/fillers/importers) can reduce it effectively, for example by lightweighting,<br />

material switching or alternative logistical processes.<br />

One report identified the so-called financing need <strong>of</strong> different systems and suggested<br />

that for the German system, this is far greater than that in the UK, France or the<br />

Netherlands (see Table 13-9). The costs considered, however, clearly do not account<br />

properly for the costs born by taxpayers and companies for the collection <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging, but only the funds which are required to be paid under the scheme being<br />

operated. Hence, they show the costs falling mostly upon the fillers/importers. This<br />

highlights, however, the difference between systems in the extent to which they are<br />

likely to lead to costs being passed onto the consumer through the price <strong>of</strong> products<br />

and services (rather than through taxation).<br />

29/09/09


Table 13-9: Financing Sources for Recycling <strong>of</strong> Household Packaging, 2000<br />

249<br />

€ € per per tonne tonne sorted sorted France France Germany Germany<br />

NL NL<br />

UK UK<br />

Tax payers/charities 41 0 53 -10<br />

Fillers/importers 40 315 0 0<br />

Packaging chain 0 0 0.08 38<br />

Source: Taylor Nelson S<strong>of</strong>res (2000) Cost-Efficiency Of Packaging Recovery Systems- the Case Of<br />

France, Germany, The Netherlands And The United Kingdom, Report for the European Commission,<br />

February 2000.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the features <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility systems is that other things being<br />

equal, the greater the proportion <strong>of</strong> costs which are placed upon producers, the closer<br />

the system is likely to come to one where pricing delivers efficient outcomes. This is<br />

especially true where a) the requirement to fund a more-or-less universal recycling<br />

service exists (or, what amounts to an equivalent requirement, the target recycling<br />

rate is high), and b) PBU systems are in place. In these cases, households are faced<br />

with the costs <strong>of</strong> the recycling services through their purchases, and are then<br />

effectively incentivised to use the ‘already paid for’ recycling service in preference to<br />

the residual waste bin through the PBU system.<br />

13.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

In Germany, the revised packaging ordinance (1998) introduced responsibility at the<br />

level <strong>of</strong> individual organisations. Retailers and other members can choose whether<br />

they take back packing waste themselves (or supported by waste management<br />

companies) or join a comparable system to the DSD, or the DSD itself.<br />

The Green Dot image is intended to denote products whose producers are a part <strong>of</strong><br />

the recycling system to reduce free-riders. However, as separation <strong>of</strong> products is<br />

done by householders, non-Green Dot branded items can find their way into this<br />

recycling stream.<br />

In Japan there is no equivalent to the Green Dot and the only defence against free<br />

riders is that the Japanese Containers and Packaging Recycling Association publish<br />

the names <strong>of</strong> producers that have performed their obligation on its website.<br />

The UK has fines for non-compliance (e.g. £10,000 for avoiding packaging costs <strong>of</strong><br />

£3,500) 263 , and the clear cut administration by a single organisation (Environment<br />

Agency in England and Wales) also helps enforcement.<br />

13.12 Lessons Learned<br />

If the policy is aimed towards household packaging, as for example in Germany, then<br />

the overall cost <strong>of</strong> recycling is higher, whereas if industry can choose the source <strong>of</strong><br />

263 Article in PackagingNews.co.uk, 26 September 2008,<br />

http://www.packagingnews.co.uk/news/849282/Renoir-Shoes-fined-breaching-pack-wasteregulations/<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


ecycling to meet its targets (such as in the UK) then the cheapest sources will be<br />

addressed first. As recycling targets are increased then the cheaper – commercial<br />

and industrial sectors – will have to be supplemented by household recycling, and the<br />

higher cost <strong>of</strong> collection will increase the overall cost (which will then be passed onto<br />

the consumer).<br />

One report that examined the cost effectiveness <strong>of</strong> packaging recycling concluded<br />

that amongst France, Germany, the Netherlands and the UK, Germany accrued the<br />

greatest environmental benefits and recycling rates but at a higher cost per unit. 264<br />

This is likely to be inevitable as the recycling performance improves as this<br />

necessarily implies having to collect packaging from higher cost sources. It does not<br />

necessarily imply that such collections should not be undertaken.<br />

Indeed, the above analysis suggests that, not only in terms <strong>of</strong> principles, but also,<br />

potentially in respect <strong>of</strong> performance, schemes which require producers to fund 100%<br />

<strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> collection <strong>of</strong> household packaging, and which require services to be<br />

provided to all householders, are likely to deliver highest performance. Without strong<br />

coverage <strong>of</strong> households, rate <strong>of</strong> recycling far in excess <strong>of</strong> 60% or so are likely to be<br />

more difficult to achieve. The top 3 performing countries – Austria, Germany and<br />

Belgium – also all make widespread use <strong>of</strong> PBU schemes at the household level.<br />

Another message is that recycling <strong>of</strong> packaging does, where logistics are efficient,<br />

deliver environmental benefits. These have been well documented in respect <strong>of</strong> GHG<br />

emissions, though our analysis suggests they apply equally in terms <strong>of</strong> non-GHG air<br />

pollutants (see Annex 63.0).<br />

Key recommendations from the Packflow 2008 report for the UK were as follows: 265<br />

i) Non Non-compliance Non compliance penalties penalties. penalties<br />

The packaging regulations should be amended at the<br />

earliest opportunity to introduce a mechanism for dealing with non-compliance by<br />

imposing non-criminal tonnage-related financial penalty charges on compliance<br />

schemes and producers that fail to meet their obligations. The revenue from these<br />

charges should be used to enhance UK packaging recycling and recovery.<br />

ii) Targets Targets. Targets . Business Targets for the years 2006 to 2008 should be calculated from<br />

the estimates in the likely growth <strong>of</strong> obligated tonnage. In addition the Government<br />

should adopt a process, ideally not requiring continual amendment <strong>of</strong> regulations, to<br />

set 5-year rolling targets extending beyond 2008 and allowing targets to be managed<br />

through regular annual review.<br />

iii) Packaging Packaging obligation obligation and and recovery recovery data data. data There is a need for more accurate and<br />

timely data and it is essential if sound target setting and review is to be<br />

accomplished.<br />

264 Taylor Nelson S<strong>of</strong>res, 2000 Cost-Efficiency Of Packaging Recovery Systems- the Case Of France,<br />

Germany, The Netherlands And The United Kingdom, Report for the European Commission, Feb 2000.<br />

265 Adapted from the Packflow 2008 report,<br />

http://www.valpak.co.uk/docs/packaging/packflow_2008_summary_report_recommendations.pdf<br />

250<br />

29/09/09


iv) Operational Operational Operational Plans Plans & & & Business Business Plans Plans. Plans Operational Plans and Business Plans<br />

prepared by compliance schemes and accredited reprocessors should be subject to<br />

much closer scrutiny, and should demonstrate the extent to which they are directly<br />

linked to the expansion <strong>of</strong> packaging recovery from local authority collections and<br />

other sources.<br />

v) Consistency Consistency in in interpretation<br />

interpretation. interpretation There needs to be improved consistency in the ways<br />

in which agency guidance and protocols are applied and interpreted by reprocessors.<br />

vi) Recycling Recycling Credits Credits. Credits Steps should be taken to improve local authority packaging<br />

recycling, expand municipal waste recycling and the recovery <strong>of</strong> ‘away from home’<br />

packaging by encouraging third parties to provide high-performing enhanced recycling<br />

facilities through the wider payment <strong>of</strong> recycling credits.<br />

vii) PRN/PERN PRN/PERN PRN/PERN fraud fraud The positive activities undertaken by the enforcement agencies<br />

to combat and eliminate PRN fraud should be continued and, where possible,<br />

strengthened to counter temptations to engage in fraudulent transactions as targets<br />

and prices rise and recycling markets tighten.<br />

In Italy, there was a debate around whether the producer responsibility organisation<br />

should cover only the extra cost (over and above the existing services) or the full cost<br />

<strong>of</strong> separate collection <strong>of</strong> packaging waste. 266 This question <strong>of</strong> interpretation has a<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>ound impact on the level <strong>of</strong> financial support to the municipalities and therefore<br />

the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the scheme. Clearly a lesson to learn is for legislation/regulations<br />

to be specific, such that the producer responsibility organisation gives the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

financial help that the government desires.<br />

13.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

The introduction <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility legislation requires the following policy<br />

details to be determined:<br />

251<br />

� Decision on type: dual system (collection <strong>of</strong> packaging alongside municipal<br />

collection e.g. DSD); recycling/recovery support (e.g. UK model); tax based<br />

systems, etc.. This decision on the nature <strong>of</strong> scheme is likely to be linked to<br />

questions regarding the distribution <strong>of</strong> costs to be visited upon the obligated<br />

producers;<br />

� Single or multiple compliance organisations. This will be a balance between<br />

economies <strong>of</strong> scale (e.g. purchasing power) and risks <strong>of</strong> monopoly<br />

inefficiencies;<br />

� Proportion <strong>of</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong> the overall obligation to be visited upon each actor<br />

in the supply chain (e.g. producer, filler, importer etc);<br />

� Decisions concerning recycling rates / service obligations;<br />

� Methodology for calculating fees. There has been surprisingly little innovation<br />

in this regard, with costs being the principle consideration. It could be argued<br />

266 Personal communication with Enzo Favoino, Scuola Agraria del Parco di Monza, June 2009.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


252<br />

29/09/09<br />

that these costs ought to incorporate some measure related to the<br />

environmental consequences associated with the use <strong>of</strong> different materials,<br />

and to reflect reprocessing destinations; 267<br />

� Method for dealing with free riders;<br />

� Means to incentivise / regulate for / establish targets for packaging waste<br />

prevention; and<br />

� Whether or not there is to be a de minimis threshold for producers taking on<br />

an obligation.<br />

267 Current discussions in the UK include the question as to whether or not to introduce differentiation<br />

in the PRN price according to whether e.g. glass is recycled through closed loop or open loop systems.<br />

This reflects the overwhelming weight <strong>of</strong> evidence which suggests that the environmental benefits <strong>of</strong><br />

the former far exceed those <strong>of</strong> the latter (see, for example, Enviros (2003) Glass Recycling – Life Cycle<br />

Carbon Dioxide Emissions, internal report for the British Glass Public Affairs Committee).


14.0 Producer Responsibility, Packaging -<br />

Germany<br />

14.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The first Packaging Ordinance, 1990, introduced a new mechanism – the take-back<br />

obligation in the packaging chain and in specific cases an obligatory deposit. It was<br />

not intended to realise this take-back obligation in the sales outlets themselves since<br />

this approach is costly, and hence, unpopular with retailers. Instead it was agreed<br />

upon in advance to install a “dual waste management system” for packaging waste<br />

parallel to the rest <strong>of</strong> municipal waste management system (the Duales System<br />

Deutschland GmbH - DSD). Participation in this system exempts the retailers from the<br />

take-back obligation as long as the system fulfils specific conditions (countrywide<br />

operation, kerbside collection, meeting recycling targets).<br />

The German Packaging Ordinance requires that no later than 31 December 2008, the<br />

annual share <strong>of</strong> all packaging waste being recovered shall be at least 65 percent by<br />

weight and the share being recycled (st<strong>of</strong>fliche Verwertung) shall be at least 55<br />

percent by weight. The recycling targets for the different materials contained in all<br />

packaging shall be 15 percent by weight for wood, 22.5 for plastics, counting<br />

exclusively material that is recycled back into plastics (either bottle to bottle or into<br />

other materials such as wood substitute for furniture), 50 for metals and 60 for glass,<br />

paper and board (Art. 1 para 3 Packaging Ordinance).<br />

For the recycling (st<strong>of</strong>fliche Verwertung) <strong>of</strong> sales packaging arising at private<br />

households the German Packaging Ordinance sets targets for manufacturers and<br />

distributors participating in a dual system and these are shown in Table 14-1 (see Art.<br />

6 para 3 and Annex I Packaging Ordinance).<br />

Table 14-1: Recycling Targets for Sales Packaging According to German Packaging<br />

Ordinance<br />

253<br />

Materi Material Materi Materi al<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Packaging Packaging in in percent percent by by weight weight to to be be recycled recycled<br />

recycled<br />

on on average average per per year<br />

year<br />

Glass 75%<br />

Tinplate 70%<br />

Aluminium 60%<br />

Paper, cardboard 70%<br />

Composites 60%<br />

Formerly the Packaging Ordinance had no individual responsibility mechanisms<br />

forcing an individual retailer, producer or filler to meet their obligations. It was<br />

sufficient that they <strong>of</strong>fered the take-back to customers even if the take-back <strong>of</strong>fer was<br />

just theoretical as far as its practical use was concerned. The enforcement<br />

mechanism was a collective one that inevitably produced free riders.


The revision <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Ordinance in 1998 introduced responsibility at the level<br />

<strong>of</strong> individual organisations. Retailers and other members could choose whether they<br />

would take back packaging waste themselves (or supported by waste management<br />

companies), or join a comparable system to the DSD (a dual system), or the DSD<br />

itself, as before. The principle change was that they now had to provide pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

compliance with the quantitative demands <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Ordinance through the<br />

measures they have taken (where they do not join a system).<br />

The Green Dot is an internationally registered trade mark. In its early years, it was<br />

used as a PR-Symbol to make the DSD-system popular for separate collection. It<br />

simply shows that the producer or distributor <strong>of</strong> the packaging has paid licence fees<br />

to DSD (or another Green Dot system). It is not a ‘recycling guarantee’ and does not<br />

imply anything about the specific qualities <strong>of</strong> the packaging itself. The Green Dot<br />

provides a check as to whether license fees for the packaging have been paid. Being<br />

a registered trade mark, any use <strong>of</strong> the Green Dot constitutes a legal relation between<br />

the user and the organisation holding the property rights <strong>of</strong> the trade mark. In any<br />

case <strong>of</strong> misuse, a claim in court has a sound legal basis. Therefore the trade mark<br />

character <strong>of</strong> the Green Dot is one precondition for managing the free rider problem.<br />

14.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

In the late Eighties and early Nineties, the debate concerning the so-called “waste<br />

emergency” raged all over Germany. At the time, authorities, the economy, the media<br />

and the public feared that in the near future, it would be extremely difficult to find<br />

sufficient disposal outlets in many regions (especially in regions with a high density <strong>of</strong><br />

population and in those with a intense concern for environmental issues). As a result,<br />

the government was very much aware <strong>of</strong> the need to find solutions which could<br />

address the emergency. Against this background, the Federal Government decided to<br />

introduce the Packaging Ordinance, with the implementation <strong>of</strong> the DSD to foster<br />

waste prevention and recycling.<br />

14.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The Packaging Ordinance gives producers and retailers and obligation to take-back<br />

their packaging material unless they join the DSD or a comparable system. If they<br />

choose not to be part <strong>of</strong> such a system, they have to manage the recycling system<br />

themselves. Otherwise, the organisations managing the take-back-system, such as<br />

the DSD, take over the product responsibility and along with it the management <strong>of</strong> the<br />

material.<br />

Besides DSD, the dual systems operating in Germany are shown in Table 14-2<br />

(according to their share in contract and licences <strong>of</strong> dual systems).<br />

The DSD is the operating company responsible for the widespread separate collection<br />

system in Germany. Companies who printed the Green dot on their products have to<br />

pay a licence fee to DSD. However, collection, transport and sorting <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

waste are not accomplished by the DSD itself. The DSD commissions other waste<br />

management enterprises through tendering processes.<br />

254<br />

29/09/09


Table 14-2: Operators <strong>of</strong> Dual Systems in Germany 2009<br />

255<br />

Company Company Market Market share share for for glas glass glas<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Market Market share share share for for<br />

for<br />

lightweight<br />

lightweight<br />

packaging packaging (LWP)<br />

(LWP)<br />

Market Market share share share for for<br />

for<br />

paper paper paper and and<br />

and<br />

cardboard cardboard<br />

cardboard<br />

DSD GmbH 55.83% 57.73% 71.6%<br />

ISD Interseroh GmbH 16.37% 11.17% 5.3%<br />

Landbell AG 3.84% 2.87% 4.0%<br />

Eko-Punkt GmbH 18.11% 21.37% 16.1%<br />

VfW Repak DS 1 0.00% 0.00% 0.0%<br />

BellandDual 2.87% 3.87% 2.9.%<br />

Redual 2.71% 2.87% 0.0%<br />

Zentek DSZ 0.27% 0.12% 0.1%<br />

Veolia Dual 1 0.00% 0.00% 0.0%<br />

1 = started to operate 2009<br />

Source: Data from the Clearing house for the forth quarter (Oct. - Dec.) 2008. 268<br />

The DSD is forced by the Packaging Ordinance to hand over detailed statistics on the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> packaging, and the amount recycled, on an annual basis to the ministries<br />

for environment <strong>of</strong> the German Länder. Furthermore the DSD publishes, voluntarily,<br />

the summary statistics for the whole <strong>of</strong> Germany. To do this, DSD collects the data<br />

from the licensed partners <strong>of</strong> DSD (recycling and disposal companies).<br />

There is no obligation to show figures which address waste prevention effects<br />

separately (i.e. reduction <strong>of</strong> waste quantities). It is, <strong>of</strong> course, a difficult task to<br />

separate the waste prevention effects <strong>of</strong> the DSD from the effects <strong>of</strong> other influences.<br />

14.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

Prognos AG (2002) Assessment <strong>of</strong> Sustainability and the Perspectives <strong>of</strong> the DSD,<br />

commissioned by the Duales System Deutschland AG, Düsseldorf, June 2002.<br />

Öko-Institut (2002) Advantage <strong>of</strong> the Green Dot for the Environment, commissioned<br />

by the Duales System Deutschland AG, Düsseldorf, March 2002.<br />

Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen, SRU)<br />

Environmental Report (“Umweltgutachten”) 2008, July 2008 (See:<br />

http://www.umweltrat.de for further information).<br />

268 EUWID from 7.01.2009, p. 7.


14.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

14.5.1 Effects on <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

Aside from the effects <strong>of</strong> the DSD on enhancement <strong>of</strong> recycling or energy recovery<br />

quotas for packaging waste (see below), two different studies claim positive effects <strong>of</strong><br />

the DSD on waste prevention (i.e. <strong>of</strong> reducing its amount and its hazardousness).<br />

The Prognos AG calculated an 18 % decrease between 1991 and 2000 (1.6 Million<br />

tonnes per annum in 2000) <strong>of</strong> packaging material in Germany caused by the DSD<br />

system. 269 The figure was created by a hypothetical calculation <strong>of</strong> the packaging<br />

material developments with, and without, the existence <strong>of</strong> the DSD. The experts <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Prognos AG underscored the decoupling <strong>of</strong> the amount <strong>of</strong> packaging material from<br />

GDP growth in Germany.<br />

The second study was carried out by the Öko-Institut commissioned by the DSD. 270<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> the in depth work showed a 4 % absolute decrease <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

material in Germany over the period <strong>of</strong> time 1990 – 1999. The Öko-Institut pointed<br />

out, that this decline followed a long period <strong>of</strong> continuous increases in packaging<br />

material and packaging waste. Furthermore the Netherlands (without a system like<br />

DSD) showed an increase <strong>of</strong> packaging material (15 – 20%) over the same time<br />

period. The Öko-Institut assumed that the relative effect (against the growth in the<br />

Netherlands) <strong>of</strong> the DSD on waste prevention could be as high as 25 %. However, the<br />

experts <strong>of</strong> the Öko-Institut suggested deeper investigations <strong>of</strong> waste prevention and<br />

the effects <strong>of</strong> DSD would be required to obtain a clearer picture.<br />

The task <strong>of</strong> isolating the effects <strong>of</strong> the DSD on waste prevention is not trivial because<br />

various other developments and influences (GDP growth, trends in the packaging<br />

sector such as usage <strong>of</strong> PET instead <strong>of</strong> glass, light weighting <strong>of</strong> packaging) must be<br />

taken into account.<br />

14.5.2 Effects on Recycling<br />

In addition to the hypothesised prevention <strong>of</strong> packaging waste, the recycling <strong>of</strong> the<br />

material collected by the DSD has significant effects in terms <strong>of</strong> the reduction <strong>of</strong> CO2<br />

emissions. According to the DSD, the take-back-system led to a reduction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

equivalent <strong>of</strong> 1.5 million tons <strong>of</strong> CO2 in 2007 and 1.4 million tons <strong>of</strong> CO2 in 2008 (see<br />

Table 14-3). 271<br />

Furthermore the DSD System has had a marked impact on other fractions <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste – especially goods made <strong>of</strong> plastic and metals which are not<br />

packaging materials. People <strong>of</strong>ten place these plastic goods (plastic cups, spoons<br />

etc.) at the end <strong>of</strong> their life in the yellow bag (and not the conventional waste bin)<br />

269 Assessment <strong>of</strong> Sustainability and the Perspectives <strong>of</strong> the DSD, Prognos AG, commissioned by the<br />

Duales System Deutschland AG, Düsseldorf, June 2002.<br />

270 Advantage <strong>of</strong> the Green Dot for the Environment, Öko-Institut, commissioned by the Duales System<br />

Deutschland AG, Düsseldorf, March 2002.<br />

271 DSD Press Release “Recycling rate on a record level”, from 1.9.2008.<br />

256<br />

29/09/09


provided by the DSD. Through the DSD system, those materials are also becoming<br />

input streams for recycling plants.<br />

Table 14-3: DSD Key Figures for 2007 and 2008<br />

257<br />

Characteristic Characteristic<br />

Effect Effect 2007 Effect Effect 2008<br />

2008<br />

Licensed quantity <strong>of</strong> sales packaging<br />

Sales packaging recovered<br />

Primary energy saved thanks to recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

sales packaging<br />

Greenhouse Gas Emissions Avoided<br />

(expressed in CO2 equivalents)<br />

Source: DSD www.gruener-punkt.de.<br />

14.6 Implementation Costs<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

approx. 2.93 million<br />

tonnes<br />

approx. 3.32 million<br />

tonnes<br />

approx. 2.6 million<br />

tonnes<br />

68.5 billion megajoules 59 5 billion megajoules<br />

1.5 million tonnes CO2<br />

1.4 million tonnes CO2<br />

Regarding the implementation costs <strong>of</strong> the DSD GmbH in the first years (from 1993<br />

until 1997) the costs for the system were almost 3 Billion German Mark (about 1,5<br />

Billion Euro) and rose up to 4.2 Billion German Mark (about 2.1 Billion Euro) in 1997<br />

at the peak <strong>of</strong> system costs (see Figure 14-1).<br />

Figure 14-1: Costs <strong>of</strong> Dual System and Amount <strong>of</strong> Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Recovered (1993<br />

- 2000)<br />

Amount <strong>of</strong> Packaging material<br />

recovered in thousand tonnes<br />

Source: DSD AG 2002<br />

Note: 1 DM = roughly 0.50 Euro Cent.<br />

System costs <strong>of</strong> the DSD in<br />

Million German Mark (DM).


The study by Prognos mentions that the DSD system would imply a financial burden<br />

for the economy and the consumers relative to an alternative system based on<br />

incineration and landfilling. 272<br />

The Öko-Institut concluded that the criticism levelled against the DSD on financial<br />

grounds did not take into account the significant external benefits associated with the<br />

system relative to alternative forms <strong>of</strong> waste treatment.<br />

14.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

In the first years <strong>of</strong> the implementation <strong>of</strong> DSD, the lack <strong>of</strong> recycling capacity in<br />

Germany led to abuses such as illegal export <strong>of</strong> DSD-<strong>Waste</strong> to Asia. Due to the legal<br />

take-back and recycling duties as well as the duty to pay for the use <strong>of</strong> Green Dot<br />

system, money was raised to be spent on the development <strong>of</strong> recycling technologies<br />

and recycling capacities. Due to the generally low value <strong>of</strong> post-consumer packaging<br />

plastics, without the DSD funding system, the above mentioned investments would<br />

have not taken place.<br />

Technical changes and innovation raised by the introduction <strong>of</strong> a Dual System have<br />

taken place on all levels <strong>of</strong> the system. In the first half <strong>of</strong> the 90’s the packaging<br />

manufacturers reduced the specific weight <strong>of</strong> packaging and removed superfluous<br />

packaging. Throughout the nineties the sorting-technology for light weight packaging<br />

(LWP) improved significantly: from mainly manual sorting to semi-automatic sorting. In<br />

a next step, fully automatic sorting technologies with integrated refinement were<br />

introduced. Another innovation was NIR (near infrared) sorters, facilitating an<br />

increase in homogeneous plastic fractions. Concerning the reprocessing <strong>of</strong> recycled<br />

material, the recycling <strong>of</strong> used PET-bottles to new PET-bottles was possible due to the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> the “bottle-to-bottle”-technology.<br />

The Prognos AG published a report in the year 2002 that suggested the DSD had<br />

created 17,000 jobs in total (this was a net figure - job cuts in some specific sectors<br />

<strong>of</strong> the economy were factored in). 273 Furthermore the study underlined the important<br />

contribution <strong>of</strong> the DSD in promoting technical innovations and investments.<br />

14.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

In the first years <strong>of</strong> the DSD, arguments against the system were very <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>of</strong> a social<br />

nature. It was argued that people would not accept that they should separate their<br />

household waste, or that the separation <strong>of</strong> waste was not acceptable to those who<br />

would have to do this. Many politicians have claimed that the end <strong>of</strong> the DSD system<br />

and the “yellow bag” was imminent, stretching back to 1990. Nevertheless the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> the population has learned to deal with the “yellow bag” and accepted the<br />

Green Dot system.<br />

272 See Fn. 269.<br />

273 Prognos AG (2002) Nachhaltigkeitsbewertung und Perspektiven des Dualen Systems in<br />

Deutschland, Report for DSD, 2002.<br />

258<br />

29/09/09


Following a poll in 2004, it became clear that the percentage <strong>of</strong> population who think<br />

“the Green Dot is a good thing” had risen from 27 % in 1992 to 67 % in 2004 (and<br />

has risen to 89% in 2006). 274 The percentage <strong>of</strong> the population who think negatively<br />

about the Green Dot system fell from 52 % in 1992 to 20 % in 2004 (and has fallen<br />

to 8% in 2006). 275 Therefore, many years after implementation <strong>of</strong> the DSD, such<br />

arguments have become irrelevant for the majority <strong>of</strong> the population.<br />

Nevertheless, it should be mentioned that social implications could <strong>of</strong>ten be found in<br />

housing areas dominated by large multi-occupancy residential buildings. In these<br />

areas the single household is not always rewarded for its contribution to waste<br />

prevention and recycling because the other households in the same building might<br />

not be so concerned about waste separation.<br />

Regarding the distributional consequences, at the beginning arguments against the<br />

DSD were focused around issues <strong>of</strong> “monopoly” and “inefficiency”. But the debate<br />

was mostly polemical and triggered by self-interest on the part <strong>of</strong> the different parties.<br />

There were some scandals in the early years <strong>of</strong> the system (recycling <strong>of</strong> green dot<br />

packaging waste in inappropriate plants overseas) and these contributed to damage<br />

the image <strong>of</strong> the DSD in the media.<br />

Irrespective <strong>of</strong> this opposition, the large retailers increasingly demanded the use <strong>of</strong><br />

the Green Dot by their suppliers. Suppliers refusing to do so had to risk losing their<br />

customers. The retailers had a strong interest in the build-up, and function <strong>of</strong>, the<br />

DSD because otherwise they had to install the take-back <strong>of</strong> packaging in their stores,<br />

which they wanted to avoid on the basis <strong>of</strong> cost. The collective pressure mechanism<br />

<strong>of</strong> the packaging Ordinance worked well in the case <strong>of</strong> the large retailers (a small<br />

number <strong>of</strong> companies have a market share <strong>of</strong> more than 80 % in the food sector, and<br />

the market concentration is even greater in the non-food sector).<br />

The food sector is the most important for business to consumer packaging waste. In<br />

Germany consumers still have quite a strong influence over food retailers.<br />

Despite the fact that large companies in this sector are well known and very<br />

prominent in the market, the market concentration is quite low and large companies<br />

are in competition in the food sector. Therefore it is very difficult for the companies to<br />

transfer the cost <strong>of</strong> the Green Dot system to the consumers. On the other hand this<br />

means an incentive for the suppliers to act in the spirit <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility by<br />

minimizing packaging waste.<br />

Despite this the DSD claims a 36 % reduction <strong>of</strong> its overall costs (and so prices)<br />

between 1998 and 2006 following the implementation <strong>of</strong> innovative technologies<br />

and better contracts with the different recycling partners resulted. 276<br />

274 See: forsa, Gesellschaft für Sozialforschung und statistische Analysen mbH, Verbraucherbefragung<br />

zum Thema Umweltbewusstsein, 25. April 2006 (Doc. P6570/16336 Sr/Sc).<br />

275 See “Study Environment 2004“, Institut für Demoskopie Allensbach, 2004; forsa (see Fn 274).<br />

276 www.gruener-punkt.de ‘What are the costs <strong>of</strong> the Green Dot?’<br />

259<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


14.9 Complementary Policies<br />

The Packaging Ordinance defining producer responsibilities for producers <strong>of</strong><br />

Packaging complements the general regulation on waste - the Closed Substances and<br />

Recycling Act (Kreislaufwirtschafts- und Abfallgesetz). The producer responsibility<br />

regulated in Articles 22 sqq <strong>of</strong> the Closed Substances and Recycling Act commits<br />

producers and distributors to design their products in a way that prevents waste in<br />

the manufacture and usage <strong>of</strong> a product.<br />

The Packaging Ordinance should be implemented as an integrated part <strong>of</strong> other<br />

policies for household waste, especially the Landfill Ordinance (Deponie-Verordnung -<br />

DeponieV) and the pay-by-use policy.<br />

14.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The policy has shifted the society towards a better allocation <strong>of</strong> resources. Without<br />

doubt, the system incurs significant costs. However, it should be taken into account<br />

that plastic recycling is the main task <strong>of</strong> the Duales System and plastic recycling is,<br />

under normal circumstances, less attractive from an economic point <strong>of</strong> view<br />

compared to metal, or paper recycling. The price impact per product sold is small,<br />

reflecting the impact <strong>of</strong> packaging on product costs.<br />

14.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

In recent years the free rider problem has become a major issue due to a lack <strong>of</strong><br />

enforcement. In 2007 the Duales System Deutschland GmbH recycled far more<br />

packaging than had been registered with the company. The total recycling rate was<br />

113 per cent (see Figure 14-2).<br />

Figure 14-2: Recycling Rates<br />

Source: DSD 2008<br />

To prevent free-riders another amendment to the packaging ordinance has been<br />

passed and will become effective on January 1 st 2009. Under this amendment all<br />

260<br />

29/09/09


packaging has to be licensed by the DSD or an equivalent system. Also, retailers have<br />

to issue a statement highlighting the level <strong>of</strong> completeness <strong>of</strong> licensing for the<br />

packaging they have distributed. Exemptions can be approved by the public agency<br />

responsible for the take-back-system. It is expected that this will lead to a<br />

strengthening <strong>of</strong> the position <strong>of</strong> the DSD as in future, nearly all packaging waste is<br />

expected to be covered by the dual system. For companies that choose selfmanagement<br />

<strong>of</strong> packaging waste disposal, there is no free rider protection.<br />

14.12 Lessons Learned<br />

Despite the sometimes negative image presented by commentators, the DSD is<br />

working quite well in terms <strong>of</strong> resource efficiency. The positive effects are mainly in<br />

the enhanced recycling rates. Positive effects on waste prevention must be proven by<br />

further in-depth analysis on this issue.<br />

The system has been criticised, not without some justification, for being expensive.<br />

Not all <strong>of</strong> this criticism has been well-informed, but it is almost certainly true to say<br />

that in early days, contracts which were entered into by the DSD were not necessarily<br />

competitively priced. Matters appear to have improved somewhat over time, but the<br />

costs remain high. In one OECD document, Ingham notes: 277<br />

261<br />

Where recycling is economically viable, as it is with aluminium and steel<br />

materials because <strong>of</strong> the high value <strong>of</strong> raw materials and the relatively low<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> processing, and where low processing costs and efficient markets<br />

make recycling feasible, government mandates may push industries to reduce<br />

packaging waste without enormous economic disruptions. However, when<br />

recycling faces higher technical and economic barriers, as it does with<br />

plastics, government mandates may create enormous disruptions. The costs<br />

<strong>of</strong> DSD rose as a consequence <strong>of</strong> including plastic packaging in the scheme.<br />

Thus, despite the fact that the DSD system does take a large amount <strong>of</strong><br />

plastic material out <strong>of</strong> the waste stream, it is costly.<br />

He concludes:<br />

One weakness <strong>of</strong> the German system is that its goals are not based on a costbenefit<br />

analysis and, as such the level is not chosen on the basis <strong>of</strong> an<br />

economic rationale. (The dominant hierarchy <strong>of</strong> waste management gives<br />

recycling a priority, and so to some extent is pursued for its own sake.) Whilst<br />

Germany achieves high recovery rates, the DSD system shows that this is<br />

expensive, and substantially exceeds the costs, including environmental costs,<br />

<strong>of</strong> alternative waste disposal methods. The targets set by the German<br />

government imposed have perhaps been too ambitious. High goals may be<br />

reasonable for materials like aluminium and steel where recycling is technically<br />

and economically practical, but such goals may not be practical for materials<br />

like plastics.<br />

277 Alan Ingham (2005) Improving Markets for <strong>Waste</strong> Plastics, in Improving Recycling Markets,<br />

ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)3/FINAL. Paris: OECD.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


This highlights the fact that there might be limits to what such schemes might seek to<br />

achieve. In particular, some schemes, including Flanders, have tended to limit their<br />

ambition in respect <strong>of</strong> collecting mixed non-bottle plastics, mainly on grounds <strong>of</strong> the<br />

cost related to the environmental benefits, without otherwise limiting their ambition in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> packaging waste recycling (see Section 15.5.1.2 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes).<br />

14.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

A waste management hierarchy is established in Art. 4 <strong>of</strong> the German Act for<br />

Promoting Closed Substance Cycle <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Ensuring Environmentally<br />

Compatible <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal (Kreislaufwirtschafts- and Abfallgesetz – KrW/AbfG) and<br />

also in the European <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive (75/442/EEC) in Art. 3. To comply<br />

with these clauses, waste generation must, firstly be prevented by means <strong>of</strong> reducing<br />

its amount and its hazardousness. Secondly, waste must be subjected to recycling or<br />

for energy recovery (i.e. using waste as a substitute fuel). Only in a third step, when<br />

minimisation or recovery is not possible, waste should be disposed <strong>of</strong>.<br />

Besides the waste hierarchy a legislative act is necessary that regulates the producer<br />

responsibility for a product group (e.g. like the Packaging ordinance does for<br />

packaging). Such a legislative act makes the duty concrete and binding. In this<br />

context it is important to notice that the producers are only released from their<br />

producer responsibility by the “Green Dot”, because it runs beside the normal waste<br />

collection, as long as they run the separate collection system.<br />

262<br />

29/09/09


15.0 Producer Responsibility – Flanders,<br />

Belgium<br />

15.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Extended Producer Responsibility (EPR) aims at creating an incentive for producers <strong>of</strong><br />

new products to take into account the treatment <strong>of</strong> these products when they become<br />

post-consumer waste. By redirecting or internalising the costs for the treatment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

waste to the producer <strong>of</strong> the product, the producer will have a clear financial benefit<br />

for designing products that create the least possible waste. As such, it encourages<br />

product design to be as reusable and recyclable as possible. This is also necessary<br />

since producers are required to meet designated recycling targets. While the policy <strong>of</strong><br />

EPR was designed as an incentive for waste prevention and ‘design for recyclability’, it<br />

has <strong>of</strong>ten resulted in being simply an instrument that helps finance recycling.<br />

EPR is mainly realised through the instrument <strong>of</strong> the take-back-obligation combined<br />

with recycling targets. In some cases the producers <strong>of</strong> packaging may collect and<br />

recycle or treat it themselves, and sometimes they finance third parties or<br />

municipalities to do this. Some EPR is limited to a statistical exercise, proving to the<br />

competent authority that waste has been collected and recycled. Communication and<br />

awareness campaigns to promote recycling are frequently financed by the industry<br />

bodies responsible for managing the policy.<br />

15.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

In Belgium the policy <strong>of</strong> EPR through take-back obligations was a favourite economic<br />

instrument in 1999-2004 when the green party was in the Flemish government (after<br />

2004, some smaller EPR schemes, such as those on agricultural foil and wood waste<br />

were withdrawn). EPR has been implemented for a set <strong>of</strong> waste streams which go<br />

beyond the EPR imposed by the European recycling directives (packaging, batteries,<br />

WEEE, ELV). Two systems <strong>of</strong> EPR have been developed:<br />

263<br />

� Take-back-obligations for packaging waste organised in a concerted way in<br />

cooperation with the three Belgian regions, implementing the packaging<br />

directive using the instrument <strong>of</strong> a Belgian cooperation protocol; and<br />

� Acceptance duties organised on a regional level using regional legislation and<br />

instruments, but also in consultation with the other regions. These duties are<br />

imposed for the waste streams described below. Usually an EPR is<br />

implemented through an MBO (milieubeleidsovereenkomst), an environmental<br />

policy agreement between the Flemish government and one or more sector<br />

federations, and brought into practice through an industry body. Table 15-1<br />

shows the industry bodies subject to EPR and the legal starting dates <strong>of</strong> the<br />

obligations.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 15-1: Flemish EPR systems<br />

264<br />

29/09/09<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> type type<br />

Since… Since…<br />

Since…<br />

Printed materials:<br />

� Publicity and unsolicited mail (interventiefonds oud papier)<br />

� Periodical press (diverse federations)<br />

1998<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> batteries (BEBAT) 1995<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> accumulators (RECYBAT) 1998<br />

Old and expired medication (diverse federations) 1985<br />

End <strong>of</strong> life vehicles (FEBELAUTO) 1999<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> tyres (RECYTYRE) 1999<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> from electrical and electronic equipment (RECUPEL)<br />

Phased: 1999, 2001,<br />

2003, 2004, 2005<br />

Flash torches (BEBAT) 2004<br />

Used oil (VALORLUB) 2004<br />

Animal and vegetable fats and oils (VALORFRIT) 2003<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> photochemicals (FOTINI) 2004<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> EPR for the waste streams illustrated in Table 15-1 is realised<br />

through MBOs (environmental policy agreements with producers) and the<br />

establishment <strong>of</strong> the industry bodies. Often three rather similar MBOs are established<br />

within the three Belgian regions. The activities <strong>of</strong> these bodies vary from data<br />

collection to assessing quantities <strong>of</strong> materials collected and recycled against targets;<br />

they also run awareness raising campaigns to augment separate collection and set<br />

up specific collection infrastructure.<br />

Individual compliance with the EPR-system is legally possible without contribution to<br />

an industry body. However, in practice the costs inherent in a producer individually<br />

attempting to meet the EPR requirements prevent such a course <strong>of</strong> action for most<br />

products except for very specific WEEE items.<br />

15.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The following organisations are involved in Belgium’s producer responsibility:<br />

� Competent authorities in the three regions: OVAM (public Flemish waste<br />

agency), BIM (Brussels institute for environment), DGRNE-OWD (Wallonian<br />

directorate general for natural resources and environment- Wallonian <strong>of</strong>fice for<br />

waste).<br />

� The interregional <strong>of</strong>fice on packaging waste.<br />

� The regional Parliaments as recipients <strong>of</strong> yearly reporting on the compliance<br />

with the collection and recycling targets.


265<br />

� The industrial federations that effect an environmental policy agreement with<br />

the governments.<br />

� The industry bodies specified in the frame <strong>of</strong> the policy agreements.<br />

� The individual producers <strong>of</strong> goods that have to join these notified bodies.<br />

� The individual producers <strong>of</strong> waste or the waste collectors that report to the<br />

notified bodies.<br />

� The reuse centres and the civic amenity sites that are active in the collection<br />

<strong>of</strong> EPR-wastes – the costs <strong>of</strong> which are to be remunerated.<br />

In the following paragraphs the relevant organisations and their key tasks are<br />

explained in more detail for every Flemish EPR system.<br />

15.3.1 Packaging <strong>Waste</strong><br />

In Belgium the European Packaging Directive has been translated as a take-back<br />

obligation, with producers being responsible for meeting the targets. It is up to each<br />

producer to decide how to meet the targets, whether that is via their own collection,<br />

sorting and recycling systems or via an accredited organisation.<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the take-back obligation is realised through the establishment<br />

<strong>of</strong> an interregional secretariat (IVCIE), uniting the Flemish, Walloon and Brussels<br />

Regions <strong>of</strong> Belgium, and national industry bodies FOST-Plus and VAL-I-PAC. FOST-Plus<br />

organises the collection <strong>of</strong> household waste in collaboration with the intermunicipal<br />

utility companies that organise selective collection rounds for paper, and for the<br />

combined stream <strong>of</strong> plastic packaging, metal packaging and beverage cartons. VAL-I-<br />

PAC organises mainly the data gathering on industrial packaging waste and creates<br />

incentives for companies to sort this kind <strong>of</strong> waste. The split between household and<br />

industrial waste is roughly 50/50. 278 Companies are not obliged to join one or both<br />

organisations, but can instead opt to fulfil their take-back obligations individually. In<br />

this case they have to report directly to the IVCIE.<br />

Parties responsible for household packaging that join FOST-Plus sign an open ended<br />

agreement (which can be terminated each year) with FOST-Plus. They make a yearly<br />

declaration <strong>of</strong> the weight, type and quantity <strong>of</strong> packaging they put on the Belgian<br />

market. They then pay a fee (using the Green Dot tariff) depending on the material<br />

and the weight <strong>of</strong> that material placed onto the market. Simpler declaration systems<br />

are in place for smaller companies. 279<br />

Intermunicipalities (waste management services that cover a number <strong>of</strong><br />

municipalities) are responsible for dealing with waste in their area and sign a<br />

standard five year agreement with FOST-Plus. They can either use their own collection<br />

infrastructure or contract it out to a waste management company (through a tender<br />

process managed by the intermunicipality and supervised by FOST-Plus). There is<br />

278 IVC activiteitenverslag (2007) Annual report IVCIE, Dutch.<br />

279 FOST-Plus (2007) Annual report, English version available.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


oughly a 50/50 split between those collecting themselves and those contracting it<br />

out. Intermunicipalities that choose not to collect the waste themselves consult the<br />

market using a standardised tender book, written by FOST-Plus. This ensures that the<br />

requirements and expectations <strong>of</strong> service delivery are equally met across Belgium.<br />

FOST-Plus and the intermunicipality make a joint decision as to which waste<br />

management company to use. 279<br />

Essential in the cooperation between FOST-Plus and the intermunicipal utility<br />

organisations is the idea that no costs for the collection <strong>of</strong> packaging waste should be<br />

borne by the public purse. Even if public infrastructure is used for the collection <strong>of</strong><br />

the waste, the costs have to be paid by the producers <strong>of</strong> the packaging material<br />

through FOST-Plus. In order to guarantee this principle, the IVCIE guards the<br />

application <strong>of</strong> realistic costs for the use <strong>of</strong> this infrastructure, e.g. for the use <strong>of</strong> civic<br />

amenity sites or public waste collection rounds.<br />

In turn, part <strong>of</strong> the agreement FOST-Plus provides the intermunicipalities with<br />

specifications for collection and sorting, including quality criteria. It also provides an<br />

administrative monitoring system (ProFost) which allows individual trucks to be<br />

monitored and the location <strong>of</strong> waste to be known at all times. 279<br />

The recyclers used are selected by FOST-Plus, again using a standardised tender<br />

book with detailed specifications. The selection <strong>of</strong> recyclers is supervised by joint<br />

committee <strong>of</strong> the intermunicipalities, IVCIE and FOST-Plus. The price indexation is<br />

linked to the evolution <strong>of</strong> raw materials. The recycling process is verified by<br />

independent auditors. 279<br />

Parties responsible for industrial packaging that join Val-I-Pac sign an open ended<br />

agreement (which can be terminated each year) with Val-I-Pac. They make a yearly<br />

declaration <strong>of</strong> the weight, type and quantity <strong>of</strong> packaging they put on the Belgian<br />

market. They then pay a fee in function <strong>of</strong> the total weight <strong>of</strong> the packaging, the<br />

material it is made <strong>of</strong>, and the possibility to recycle it at the end <strong>of</strong> use<br />

(www.valipac.be).<br />

15.3.2 Printed Materials<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the take-back obligation for printed materials is realised<br />

through two different MBOs: one for publicity and unsolicited mail 280 , and one for<br />

dealing with periodicals. 281 .<br />

The MBO on publicity and unsolicited mail was signed by the federations BDMV<br />

(Belgian direct marketing association, FEBELGRA (federation <strong>of</strong> the Belgian printing<br />

and communication industry), FEDIS (Belgian Federation <strong>of</strong> distributors), VEGRAB<br />

(federation <strong>of</strong> printing companies), NAVETEX (national association <strong>of</strong> textile retailers)<br />

and VDV (association <strong>of</strong> food retailers). The members <strong>of</strong> these federations all pay a<br />

contribution <strong>of</strong> €0.005 per kg paper they put on the market. These contributions are<br />

280 B.S. 10/02/99 Milieubeleidsovereenkomst papier met BDMV, FEBELGRA, FEDIS, NAVETEX, VDV en<br />

VEGRAB.<br />

281 B.S. 24/04/98 Milieubeleidsovereenkomst Papier met BVDU, NFIW, UUP en VUKPP.<br />

266<br />

29/09/09


used to reimburse (inter)municipalities for their waste paper collection through CA<br />

sites and door-to-door collection.<br />

The MBO for the periodical press was signed by BVDU (Belgian association <strong>of</strong><br />

publishers), NFIW (national association <strong>of</strong> informative magazines), UUPP<br />

(<strong>International</strong> federation <strong>of</strong> periodical press) and VUKPP (federation <strong>of</strong> catholic<br />

periodical press). The members <strong>of</strong> these federations do not have to pay a contribution<br />

for the paper they put on the market, but they have to reserve a certain amount <strong>of</strong><br />

advertisement space for the Flemish government. The aim is that the space has a<br />

total value <strong>of</strong> more than €3 million per year. By way <strong>of</strong> example, the members <strong>of</strong> NFIW<br />

have to reserve 4 pages or 8 half pages for the Flemish government. The government<br />

uses this space mainly for advertisements on prevention or recycling, and consider<br />

this as a payment ‘in kind’. There is a discussion on the environmental effect <strong>of</strong> this<br />

measure and the stimulus it creates, or does not create, for DFE and waste<br />

prevention.<br />

15.3.3 <strong>Waste</strong> Batteries<br />

In 1993, a federal Belgian tax on batteries was agreed by the Belgian Government as<br />

part <strong>of</strong> their ecotax legislation. Before this was implemented, a voluntary agreement<br />

with the industry resulted in the ecotax law for batteries: batteries were to be<br />

exempted from the ecotax when a voluntary collection and recycling scheme was<br />

established. In response, the battery industry set up the non-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation<br />

BEBAT to co-ordinate the collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> batteries, and to ensure that the<br />

target percentages were reached (collection target: 65% in 2004). The financing <strong>of</strong><br />

the 'collection and recycling contribution' is paid by members <strong>of</strong> the organisation (i.e.<br />

battery producers and distributors). This contribution is passed on to the consumers<br />

through a price increase. (€0.1239 per battery - for the connection with the Belgian<br />

ecotax, please see Section 30.5.2.2 <strong>of</strong> the Annexes).<br />

In 1997, a take-back obligation for waste batteries was implemented. The collection<br />

percentage was increased to 75%; the recycling target was set to 65%.<br />

BEBAT places collection boxes at more than 20,000 collection points (hyper- and<br />

supermarkets and local shops, jewellers, photo shops, do-it-yourself stores, toy<br />

stores, electrical stores, pharmacies, etc., as well as schools, public and private<br />

institutions, and the CA sites) at no cost for the owners <strong>of</strong> the collection points.<br />

Batteries are sorted by type: button cells; rechargeable batteries with nickelcadmium;<br />

rechargeable batteries with nickel-metalhydride; rechargeable batteries<br />

with lithium-ion; lead batteries; other types, especially alkaline and zinc-carbon<br />

batteries (being the most common).<br />

The batteries collected by BEBAT must be recycled according to the agreements<br />

signed with the three regions. For monitoring purposes, BEBAT is required to provide<br />

information to the ecotax commission, the regional governments (e.g. OVAM) and the<br />

federal government at fixed intervals. All producers <strong>of</strong> batteries in Flanders have<br />

joined BEBAT (www.bebat.be -English version available).<br />

267<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 15-1: BEBAT Collection Box for Batteries to be Placed at Point <strong>of</strong> Sale<br />

15.3.4 <strong>Waste</strong> Accumulators<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the take-back obligation for waste accumulators is realised<br />

through the MBO on waste accumulators (2003) and the establishment <strong>of</strong> RECYBAT.<br />

Like other industry bodies, RECYBAT should co-ordinate the collection and recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

the waste accumulators, finance the system, monitor and report collection and<br />

recycling targets. In practice, the activities <strong>of</strong> RECYBAT are limited to monitoring and<br />

reporting. Due to the high residual value <strong>of</strong> waste accumulators (as a result <strong>of</strong> the<br />

high price <strong>of</strong> lead), no supplementary collection system needs to be put in place. In<br />

2005, almost 95% <strong>of</strong> waste accumulators were collected spontaneously, driven by<br />

the high value <strong>of</strong> the material. The implementation <strong>of</strong> the MBO on waste<br />

accumulators did not have any affect on the collection percentage. 282<br />

15.3.5 Old and Expired Medication<br />

Between 1985 and 1994, the collection <strong>of</strong> old and expired medication was organised<br />

and coordinated by OVAM. In 1994, this collection was taken over by the<br />

pharmaceutical sector. In 1998, the first MBO on old and expired medication was<br />

implemented, and a new MBO has since been signed in 2008 which will shortly be<br />

implemented. The following federations are involved: ABP (Belgian pharmaceutical<br />

association), OPHACO (Belgian association <strong>of</strong> pharmaceutical cooperatives), NVGV<br />

(national organisation <strong>of</strong> pharmaceutical wholesalers), AVGI (Belgian pharmaceutical<br />

industry association) and FEBELGEN (generic pharmaceutical organisation).<br />

282 OVAM (2007) Evaluatie van aanvaardingsplichten (Evaluation <strong>of</strong> take-back obligations).<br />

268<br />

29/09/09


Consumers can bring old and expired medication to the local chemist. The following<br />

expired or unused medication can be handed in:<br />

269<br />

� unused tablets and capsules;<br />

� remains <strong>of</strong> creams and ointments in tubes;<br />

� syrups and liquid medication in their containers;<br />

� remains <strong>of</strong> spray/aerosol medication; and<br />

� x-ray photographic plates.<br />

The following products are not accepted:<br />

� empty glass bottles (glass collector);<br />

� empty cardboard boxes and information leaflets (paper and cardboard waste);<br />

� remains <strong>of</strong> toothpaste, shampoo, bath foam, soap, cosmetics and care<br />

products (household garbage or small hazardous household waste);<br />

� pesticides and insecticides (small hazardous waste);<br />

� used hypodermic needles (collected in a rigid container for small hazardous<br />

waste);<br />

� blister plasters (household garbage); and<br />

� band aids, bandages, cotton wool, gauzes, diapers, incontinence material, test<br />

strips, diet- and baby food (household garbage).<br />

The chemist collects the expired and unused medication in special cardboard boxes,<br />

which are picked up by the wholesalers when delivering new medication. If the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> these boxes were to be free <strong>of</strong> charge, then they would not be completely<br />

filled or they would contain products that are not subject to the MBO. If the charge on<br />

the boxes was too high, then the boxes would tend to get overfilled, making them less<br />

stackable at the wholesalers and leading to a potential safety risk. 283 Thus the<br />

chemist pays the wholesaler €1 per box for collection, reflecting a balance between<br />

high and low costs.<br />

Unlike other waste streams with take-back obligation, where a large proportion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

materials are recycled or recovered, the old and expired medication is incinerated. In<br />

2007, 3 Belgian incineration plants were responsible for the disposal <strong>of</strong> this waste<br />

medication: Siomab (Brussels), IBW (Virginal) and Ipalle (Thumaide). 283<br />

The costs <strong>of</strong> collecting and transporting the old and expired medication to the<br />

incineration plants are financed by the wholesalers; the costs for incineration are<br />

financed by the pharmaceutical industry. 284<br />

283 OVAM (2008) Oude en vervallen geneesmiddelen – Inzamelresultaten 2007 (Old and expired<br />

medication – Collection data 2007), Dutch.<br />

284 Draft MBO on old and expired medication, 2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The wholesalers report the number <strong>of</strong> boxes that are transported to the incineration<br />

plants. The pharmaceutical industry (i.e. AVGI and FEBELGEN) reports the quantity<br />

(kg) <strong>of</strong> incinerated old and expired medication and the yearly costs for incineration. 285<br />

15.3.6 End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the take-back obligation for end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles was realised<br />

through the MBO on end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles (1999, revised in 2005) and the<br />

establishment <strong>of</strong> FEBELAUTO. 286 This was set up in 1999 by car distributors and ELV<br />

treatment companies as a non-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation to ensure implementation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

MBO by organising and monitoring the management <strong>of</strong> recovery and disposal.<br />

Car dealerships must take back free <strong>of</strong> charge any ELV returned to them. The<br />

dealership will provide a certificate <strong>of</strong> acceptance in exchange for the vehicle they<br />

have received. Distributors must then accept back from the retail trade, at their own<br />

expense, all ELVs delivered to the dealerships, and pass them on to the producer or<br />

importer <strong>of</strong> that vehicle make. Producers and importers must, at their own expense,<br />

regularly collect all ELVs taken back by distributors, and if appropriate from retailers,<br />

and have them treated in an authorised centre within 6 months <strong>of</strong> receiving them.<br />

The MBO and VLAREA stipulate a few conditions that should be met for free take back<br />

<strong>of</strong> an ELV:<br />

270<br />

� The ELV contains all components indispensable for the functioning <strong>of</strong> the<br />

vehicle;<br />

� It does not contain any other waste;<br />

� It has been registered in Belgium by the last owner for at least 6 months; and<br />

� It has a registration document, a certificate <strong>of</strong> conformity, the number plate<br />

and if appropriate, the most recent technical testing certificate.<br />

Vehicle manufacturers must provide the following information annually:<br />

� The quantity <strong>of</strong> vehicles by weight and type that they have put on the market in<br />

the Flemish Region;<br />

� The quantity <strong>of</strong> vehicles by weight and type for which a Certificate <strong>of</strong><br />

Destruction has been issued;<br />

� Which treatment facility they have returned the vehicles to, and which<br />

treatment procedures have been used; and<br />

� The total amount <strong>of</strong> waste recovered, incinerated and sent to landfill.<br />

Vehicle dealerships and distributors must provide OVAM with the type and weight <strong>of</strong><br />

ELVs taken back in the previous year.<br />

285 Draft MBO on old and expired medication, 2008<br />

286 B.S. 19/04/05 Milieubeleidsovereenkomst betreffende de uitvoering van de VLAREAaanvaardingsplicht<br />

afgedankte voertuigen.<br />

29/09/09


15.3.7 <strong>Waste</strong> Tyres<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the take-back obligation for waste tyres is realised through the<br />

MBO on waste tyres (2003) and the establishment <strong>of</strong> RECYTYRE. 287<br />

RECYTYRE was founded by six <strong>of</strong> the world’s largest tyre producers in 2006. <strong>Waste</strong><br />

tyres are collected by almost 5,000 garages, tyre specialists and distributors. In some<br />

municipalities, waste tyres are also collected at CA sites. The financing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

collection is paid by the consumer (depending on the type and size <strong>of</strong> the tyre; e.g.<br />

€2.4 per tyre for cars, €12.46 per tyre for lorries and buses). RECYTYRE subsequently<br />

collects the waste tyres at the collection points (www.recytyre.be, Dutch).<br />

The operators <strong>of</strong> collection points have to take back the waste tyres for free, even if<br />

the consumer does not buy a new tyre. The collection points are exempt from this<br />

obligation, when collection <strong>of</strong> waste tyres is possible in a nearby CA sites.<br />

Like other industrial bodies, RECYTYRE is required to achieve collection and recycling<br />

percentages, to monitor and report collection and recycling percentages, to draw up<br />

prevention plans, amongst other functions.<br />

15.3.8 <strong>Waste</strong> from Electrical and Electronic Equipment<br />

Implementation <strong>of</strong> the take-back obligation for waste from electrical and electronic<br />

equipment (WEEE) is realised through the MBO on WEEE (2001) and the<br />

establishment <strong>of</strong> RECUPEL. 288 A revised MBO will be published shortly.<br />

RECUPEL was founded by the industrial federations Agoria (Federation for the<br />

technology industry) and FEE (Federation <strong>of</strong> electricity and electronics), to ensure the<br />

collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE. Information is available at www.recupel.be (English<br />

version available). These branch associations also founded sector associations, socalled<br />

RECUPEL “sectors”, each one representing a group <strong>of</strong> well-defined products:<br />

271<br />

� BW-Rec (for large household electronics);<br />

� Recupel AV (for audiovisual equipment / consumer electronics);<br />

� Recupel SDA (for small domestic appliances);<br />

� Recupel ICT (for information and communication technology);<br />

� Recupel ET / Garden (for electronic tools and garden equipment);<br />

� LightRec (for lighting equipment and gas-discharge lamps); and<br />

� MeLaRec (for medical devices and laboratory equipment).<br />

RECUPEL acts as a ‘contractor’ for these 7 RECUPEL sectors.<br />

The MBO stipulates the following obligations:<br />

287 B.S. 8/11/03 Milieubeleidsovereenkomst betreffende de uitvoering van de Vlareaaanvaardingsplicht<br />

afvalbanden.<br />

288 B.S. 1/06/01 Milieubeleidsovereenkomst betreffende de uitvoering van de VLAREAaanvaardingsplicht<br />

van afgedankte elektrische en elektronische apparatuur.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


272<br />

� Organisation <strong>of</strong> the separate collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE (responsibility lies with<br />

municipalities);<br />

� Social economy undertakings are to be included in the collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE;<br />

� Take-back <strong>of</strong> a similar product when a new product is purchased (retailer<br />

responsibility); and<br />

� Realisation <strong>of</strong> the environmentally sound treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE (producer<br />

responsibility).<br />

Each manufacturer or importer has to join a system for WEEE collection and<br />

treatment. Alternatively, manufacturers or importers may establish an individual<br />

waste management plan and have it approved by the authorities.<br />

The collection network <strong>of</strong> RECUPEL relies on the following collection points:<br />

� all 518 CA sites in Belgium (89 serviced directly, 444 serviced through<br />

regional transhipment stations);<br />

� 28 intermunicipal regional transhipment stations (‘intercommunales’);<br />

� 17 used goods centres acting as regional transhipment stations;<br />

� 2 re-distribution centres <strong>of</strong> retailers (for approximately 112 branches);<br />

� approximately 2,700 retailers; and<br />

� collection facilities such as repair companies and waste management<br />

companies.<br />

Requests for the collection and transport <strong>of</strong> household appliances from these<br />

collection points can be submitted through the RECUPEL website. The minimum<br />

amount required in order to arrange a collection is either 8 large appliances or one<br />

box pallet (for small appliances or CRT appliances). Bulk transport is organized when<br />

there is at least one full container or 24 box pallets. CA sites are also provided with<br />

so-called 'RECUPEL containers’, solely intended for the collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE. The only<br />

types <strong>of</strong> WEEE that cannot be collected at CA sites are medical devices and laboratory<br />

equipment. A tailor-made solution has been created for the collection and recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

these very specific types <strong>of</strong> WEEE.<br />

In order to safeguard the EPR principle, and to ensure that no public money is used<br />

for the collection <strong>of</strong> any WEEE for which a take back obligation exists, the costs for<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> public infrastructure such as CA sites has to be carefully assessed. The<br />

Flemish ministerial decision includes a model within the framework on EPR<br />

mechanisms on how to calculate a fair price for the use <strong>of</strong> the public infrastructure <strong>of</strong><br />

CA sites.<br />

RECUPEL works together with one main logistics partner and 6 treatment partners for<br />

WEEE in Flanders and the Walloon region, with between 2 and 4 treatment partners<br />

per product flow group.<br />

Producers and importers, via RECUPEL, must provide the following yearly information:<br />

� the amount (types, number and weight) <strong>of</strong> EEE put on the market in the<br />

Flemish Region;<br />

� the total amount <strong>of</strong> collected WEEE (types, number and weight);<br />

29/09/09


273<br />

� which treatment facilities they have returned the WEEE to and which treatment<br />

procedures have been used; and<br />

� the total amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE recovered, incinerated and sent to landfill.<br />

Distributors <strong>of</strong> EEE must provide OVAM with information on the total amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

(kg) collected per annum, and on the number and types <strong>of</strong> WEEE and their treatment<br />

specifications.<br />

15.3.9 Flash Torches<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the take-back obligation for flash torches is realised through<br />

the MBO on flash torches (2006). 289 BEBAT, the organisation responsible for the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> waste batteries, also collects flash torches. A joint collection system for<br />

waste batteries and flash torches is used (see Section 15.3.3 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes for<br />

more information on BEBAT).<br />

15.3.10 Used Oil<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the take-back obligation for used oil is realised through the<br />

MBO on used oil (2008) 290 and the establishment <strong>of</strong> VALORLUB.<br />

VALORLUB was founded in 2004 (operational since 2007) by the Belgian Petrol<br />

Federation (BPF), the Lubricants Association Belgium (LAB), the Belgian Federation <strong>of</strong><br />

distributors (Fedis) and the Belgian confederation gathering the different groupings <strong>of</strong><br />

the Belgian automotive sector (FEDERAUTO). The goal <strong>of</strong> VALORLUB is to carry out the<br />

take-back obligation imposed on the members <strong>of</strong> the founding federations.<br />

Each company subject to the take-back obligation can meet its obligations individually<br />

or can join VALORLUB. The obligations are:<br />

� For final sellers, intermediaries, producers and importers to accept used oil<br />

from their customers for free, without obligation to purchase;<br />

� For producers and importers<br />

• To have the collected oil processed at their own expense in an<br />

institution licensed for this purpose;<br />

• To obtain the stipulated percentages <strong>of</strong> collection;<br />

• To obtain the percentages <strong>of</strong> recovery; and<br />

• To inform and sensitise consumers and collectors/processors.<br />

The VALORLUB system <strong>of</strong> collection is different for domestic oil and for commercial<br />

oil. For used oil coming from householders, no take-back is organized at the point <strong>of</strong><br />

sale. The collection <strong>of</strong> domestic oil takes place through the (inter)municipalities: CA<br />

289 B.S. 28/03/06 Milieubeleidsovereenkomst betreffende de uitvoering van de terugnameplicht voor<br />

inzake zaklampen.<br />

290 B.S. 29/08/08 Milieubeleidsovereenkomst betreffende de aanvaardingsplicht voor afgewerkte olie.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


sites, collections organised within communities or door-to-door collections. VALORLUB<br />

reimburses the municipalities for the costs <strong>of</strong> using the infrastructure at the CA sites,<br />

and for the processing <strong>of</strong> this oil afterwards.<br />

Companies that produce used oils (like garages or industry) can contact any collector<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficially accredited by the government for the collection <strong>of</strong> used oils. Companies and<br />

operators are not bound by obligations imposed by VALORLUB, they merely have to<br />

follow the existing legislation on used oils. But VALORLUB can reimburse the<br />

producers <strong>of</strong> used oil if the collection is done by a collector that is also accredited by<br />

VALORLUB itself. The reimbursement depends on the market value, the quantity<br />

(


VALORFRIT reimburses the municipalities for the costs <strong>of</strong> using the infrastructure at<br />

the CA sites, and for the processing <strong>of</strong> this oil afterwards.<br />

Companies that produce animal and vegetable fats and oils (like hotels, restaurants,<br />

hospitals etc.) can contact any collector <strong>of</strong>ficially accredited by the government for the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> this material. Companies and operators are not bound by obligations<br />

imposed by VALORFRIT, they merely have to follow the existing legislation on waste<br />

animal and vegetable fats and oils. There is no reimbursement for the producers to<br />

cover the collection costs.<br />

VALORFRIT reports the percentages <strong>of</strong> collection and <strong>of</strong> useful use to OVAM.<br />

15.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

275<br />

� Aanvaardingsplichten – Referentiedocument voor milieubeleidsovereenkomsten,<br />

OVAM 2004, reference document for municipalities and<br />

companies on acceptance obligations (Dutch)<br />

� Aanvaardingsplichten in het Vlaamse Gewest, OVAM, 2008, six monthly<br />

progress report on the implementation <strong>of</strong> EPR (Dutch)<br />

� Evaluatie van de effectiviteit en de efficiëntie van het instrument<br />

aanvaardingsplichten en de invulling die er nu aan gegeven wordt met het oog<br />

op verbetering van de wetgeving, HIVA by order <strong>of</strong> OVAM, 2006, evaluation <strong>of</strong><br />

the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the EPR policy and its actual implementation in view <strong>of</strong><br />

amelioration <strong>of</strong> the legislation. (Dutch)<br />

15.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

15.5.1 Packaging <strong>Waste</strong><br />

15.5.1.1 Environmental Benefits <strong>of</strong> Prevention<br />

In 2007, collection yields <strong>of</strong> domestic packaging waste remained high. Around 63 kg<br />

<strong>of</strong> packaging were collected per capita (116 kg per capita when taking the whole<br />

waste paper segment into account). Except for a very slight decrease in arisings <strong>of</strong><br />

Plastiek- Metaal- en Drankverpakkingen(PMD), which is plastic packaging, metal<br />

packaging and composed beverage packaging (tetrabrick etc), quantities collected<br />

per material remained almost identical: 15 kg for PMD, 30 kg for glass and 70 kg for<br />

paper-cardboard (including non-packaging). 292<br />

292 Fost Plus (2007) Annual Report.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 15-2: Trend in Collection <strong>of</strong> Household Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> in Flanders<br />

(kg/capita/year)<br />

Source: Annual Report 2007, FOST Plus<br />

An analysis <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> reusable packaging in Belgium (2008) shows that the use <strong>of</strong><br />

domestic reusable packaging has diminished between 2005 and 2006. The use <strong>of</strong><br />

industrial reusable packaging (mainly glass, wood and a few new materials) has risen<br />

(see Figure 15-2). 293 - Figure 15-3 below shows the trend in packaging waste<br />

generation, in comparison with the EU15.<br />

Table 15-2: Total Quantities <strong>of</strong> Packaging in Belgium (tonnes)<br />

276<br />

29/09/09<br />

Type Type<br />

Quantity, Quantity, 2005 Quantity, Quantity, 2006<br />

Domestic non-reusable 719,000 730,000<br />

Domestic reusable 838,000 802,000<br />

Industrial non-reusable 612,000 643,000<br />

Industrial reusable 1,915,500 2,045,000<br />

293 IVCIE (2007) Annual Report.


Figure 15-3: Belgian Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Generation per Capita, 1997-2006<br />

200<br />

180<br />

160<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

277<br />

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006<br />

Source: European Environment Agency, 2009<br />

15.5.1.2 Environmental Benefits <strong>of</strong> Recycling<br />

In Flanders, the following collection scheme for household packaging is in place:<br />

� Glass: voluntary deposit, sorted by colour, approximately one site per 1,000<br />

inhabitants;<br />

� PMD (plastic bottles and flasks, metal packaging and drink cartons): door-todoor<br />

collection, twice a month, transparent blue bag (which enables<br />

contaminants to be easily identified), with subsequent sorting into several<br />

waste segments; and<br />

� Mixed paper and cardboard (packaging and waste paper): door-to-door<br />

collection<br />

To complement the above, all waste streams can also be collected via CA sites.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Belgium<br />

It was decided to collect only that which is recyclable. This ensures a homogeneous<br />

waste stream, provides sufficient quantity <strong>of</strong> recyclables which meets high quality<br />

standards, and ensures continuity <strong>of</strong> supply. The possibility <strong>of</strong> recycling mixed plastics<br />

was investigated, but it was found that the benefits were insufficient to justify the<br />

additional costs involved, i.e. it would increase overall recycling rates by 5% to 8%, but<br />

would incur an overall additional cost <strong>of</strong> 60% to 70%.<br />

Table 15-3 and Table 15-4 show that the recycling and recovery targets in Belgium<br />

are much more ambitious than the ones set across Europe (Directive 94/62/EC on<br />

packaging waste). Nevertheless, these targets were already surpassed in 2006. 294<br />

294 IVCIE (2007) Annual Report.<br />

EU15


Table 15-3 Recycling and Recovery Targets for Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> in Belgium<br />

Household Household packaging<br />

packaging<br />

278<br />

29/09/09<br />

2009<br />

2009<br />

(% (% by by weight)<br />

weight)<br />

2010<br />

2010<br />

(% (% (% by by weight)<br />

weight)<br />

Achieved Achieved 2006<br />

2006<br />

(% (% by by weight)<br />

weight)<br />

Recycled 80% 80% 82%<br />

Recovered or incinerated with<br />

energy recovery<br />

Industrial Industrial packaging<br />

packaging<br />

90% 90% 94%<br />

Recycled 75% 80% 80%<br />

Recovered or incinerated with<br />

energy recovery<br />

Source: IVCIE (2007), Annual Report<br />

80% 85% 87%<br />

Table 15-4 Recycling Targets for Materials Contained in Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> (Annual<br />

Report 2007, IVCIE)<br />

Material Material<br />

Target Target (% (% by by weight) weight)<br />

Achieved Achieved (2006)<br />

(2006)<br />

Glass 60% 99.8%<br />

Paper and board 60% 89.1%<br />

Metals 50% 93.2%<br />

Plastics (counting exclusively<br />

material that is recycled back<br />

into plastics)<br />

30% 38.5%<br />

Wood 15% 63.8%<br />

Following FOST-Plus, the key factors for the success <strong>of</strong> the Belgium packaging waste<br />

management system are:<br />

� A close public-private partnership – a successful collaboration between:<br />

• Regions;<br />

• Municipalities and intermunicipal authorities;<br />

• Industry (via FOST-Plus and Val-I-Pac);<br />

• Private waste operators; and<br />

• Most importantly: citizens.<br />

� Active participation <strong>of</strong> people in separating their packaging;<br />

� Rational and optimised collection scenario;<br />

� Acceptable cost for industry and striking the balance between price and<br />

quality;<br />

� Implementation in phases (10 years to implement across the country);<br />

� Strong communication;<br />

� High cost for residual waste;


279<br />

� Widespread use <strong>of</strong> PBU;<br />

� Transparency; and<br />

� Well managed tenders for collection, sorting, and recycling.<br />

Selective collection <strong>of</strong> industrial packaging is stimulated by 2 incentives for<br />

companies that joined Val-I-Pac (www.valipac.be ):<br />

� Recycling incentive:<br />

• Plastics: 40 Euro per tonne<br />

• Wood: 10 Euro per tonne<br />

� Container incentive, for example:<br />

• Containers <strong>of</strong> 1000 litres or more: 110 Euro per year;<br />

• Containers 660 to 999 litres: 60 Euro per year; and<br />

• Collection bags for plastics (> 200 l) or EPS (expanded polystyrene) ><br />

500 l: 0.5 Euro per year.<br />

15.5.2 Printed Materials<br />

15.5.2.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

The MBO on publicity and unsolicited mail stipulates the following obligations with<br />

regard to prevention:<br />

� Reduction <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> plastic packaging;<br />

� Use <strong>of</strong> environmentally sound ink and paper;<br />

� Respect for the stickers against unsolicited mail for post boxes; and<br />

� Reduction <strong>of</strong> the amount <strong>of</strong> unsolicited mail.<br />

The MBO for the periodical press stipulates similar obligations.<br />

No evaluation report is available.<br />

15.5.2.2 Environmental Benefits Recycling<br />

Both MBOs stipulate that the paper that is used for mail and periodical press contains<br />

at least 40% <strong>of</strong> recycled fibre.<br />

No evaluation report is available.<br />

15.5.3 <strong>Waste</strong> Batteries<br />

15.5.3.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

The Flemish regulation for waste (VLAREA) includes several actions, such as limits on<br />

the quantities <strong>of</strong> cadmium and lead in batteries. VLAREA stipulates, literally, that<br />

these actions are intended to stimulate the use <strong>of</strong> rechargeable batteries. The MBO<br />

on waste batteries, however, makes no reference at all to the stimulation <strong>of</strong> the use<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


<strong>of</strong> rechargeable batteries. According to the industry, there is no scientific pro<strong>of</strong> that<br />

rechargeable batteries would be better than non rechargeable batteries from an<br />

ecological point <strong>of</strong> view.<br />

Nevertheless, the number <strong>of</strong> rechargeable batteries has increased four-fold from<br />

1997 to 2005. In addition, the maximum limits on the quantities <strong>of</strong> cadmium<br />

(


Figure 15-4: Collection for Recycling <strong>of</strong> Batteries since the Introduction <strong>of</strong> an EPR on<br />

Batteries in Belgium (BEBAT).<br />

Note: Andere (light green) = ‘other’<br />

15.5.4 <strong>Waste</strong> Accumulators<br />

15.5.4.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

RECYBAT reports no prevention actions: there are no producers <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

accumulators in Belgium, so ecodesign in Flanders is not an option. The importers<br />

have little influence on the design <strong>of</strong> the batteries. 299<br />

Reuse is not an option.<br />

15.5.4.2 Environmental Benefits Recycling<br />

Table 15-5 shows the collection and recycling targets that are in force. 300<br />

Table 15-5 Collection and recycling percentages <strong>of</strong> waste accumulators<br />

281<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Target Target<br />

Achieved Achieved (2005)<br />

(2005)<br />

Collection 95% 93.7%<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> lead 95% 95%<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> plastics 30% 36%<br />

Source: OVAM, 2007<br />

299 OVAM (2007) Evaluatie van aanvaardingsplichten (Evaluation <strong>of</strong> take-back obligations), in Dutch.<br />

300 OVAM (2007) Evaluatie van aanvaardingsplichten (Evaluation <strong>of</strong> take-back obligations), in Dutch.


15.5.5 <strong>Waste</strong> Tyres<br />

15.5.5.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

RECYTYRE makes no report on prevention.<br />

15.5.5.2 Environmental Benefits Recycling<br />

There are almost 5,000 tyre collection sites in Belgium. In 2007, they collected about<br />

80,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste tyres. In Flanders, about 51,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste tyres were<br />

collected, which amounts to a collection percentage <strong>of</strong> 92.34%. The collection target<br />

is 100%.<br />

Flemish legislation sets a recycling target for waste tyres <strong>of</strong> 25%, a disposal with<br />

energy recovery target <strong>of</strong> 55% and a re-treading target <strong>of</strong> 25%. In 2007, RECYTYRE<br />

reported a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 47.5% and a disposal rate with energy recovery <strong>of</strong> 42%.<br />

The re-treading rate was not achieved, however. In 2007, a re-treading rate <strong>of</strong> only 8%<br />

was achieved. The ETRA report ‘Introduction to Tyre Recycling: 2006’ shows that the<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> re-treading in Europe has averaged 11 to 13% since 1992. This certainly is a<br />

point <strong>of</strong> concern for Belgium/Flanders. 301<br />

15.5.6 Old and Expired Medication<br />

15.5.6.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

According to the MBO, local chemists are required to advise their customers on the<br />

correct usage <strong>of</strong> medication. In doing so, the purchase <strong>of</strong> new medication might be<br />

prevented, and the amount <strong>of</strong> unused/expired medication reduced.<br />

15.5.6.2 Environmental Benefits Recycling<br />

Not relevant. The aim <strong>of</strong> the take back obligation for old and expired medication is not<br />

to recycle the waste, but to guarantee its safe treatment in an appropriate<br />

installation.<br />

15.5.7 End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

15.5.7.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

Prevention is limited to qualitative prevention.<br />

15.5.7.2 Environmental Benefits Recycling<br />

In Flanders, more than 73,000 end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles (ELV) were collected and<br />

decommissioned. The recycling targets to be reached are:<br />

282<br />

� by January 2006, reuse and recovery <strong>of</strong> 85% by weight per vehicle, and reuse<br />

and recycling <strong>of</strong> 80%;<br />

301 OVAM (2008) Internal Report On <strong>Waste</strong> Tyres, Dutch.<br />

29/09/09


283<br />

� by January 2015, reuse and recovery <strong>of</strong> 95% by weight per vehicle, and reuse<br />

and recycling <strong>of</strong> 85%.<br />

In 2007, almost 90% <strong>of</strong> the weight <strong>of</strong> the vehicle was recovered in Flanders. The<br />

recycling rate amounted to 68% and the reuse rate amounted to 19.8%. 302<br />

In order to allow separate treatment to be carried out and the above recycling/reuse<br />

targets to be fulfilled, manufacturers and importers must prepare dismantling<br />

information for each new type <strong>of</strong> vehicle within six months <strong>of</strong> it first being placed on<br />

the market, including information on individual components and materials and where<br />

hazardous substances are located.<br />

Manufacturers are to make information on dismantling, storage and testing <strong>of</strong><br />

reusable components available to dismantling facilities upon request.<br />

Authorised centres enter data such as the relevant date, number and weight <strong>of</strong> ELVs,<br />

and the type and weight <strong>of</strong> waste streams, after decommissioning, into a national<br />

database. The database is managed by FEBELAUTO.<br />

A problem that has not yet been solved is the illegal export <strong>of</strong> ELVs as second-hand<br />

cars, <strong>of</strong>ten to Eastern Europe or the west coast <strong>of</strong> Africa. In Belgium, there is no link<br />

between the registration number <strong>of</strong> the car and the car owner, so an ELV cannot be<br />

traced to his <strong>of</strong> her owner. For several years, the Flemish government has been<br />

pleading with the federal government to update the registry system, but so far nothing<br />

has been changed. An additional control mechanism would be to ensure certificates<br />

<strong>of</strong> destruction (CoD) are issued with every vehicle deregistration in the region.<br />

15.5.8 <strong>Waste</strong> from Electrical and Electronic Equipment<br />

15.5.8.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

The MBO stipulates the following actions for producers:<br />

� Use <strong>of</strong> easy-to-recycle materials;<br />

� Prevention <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances;<br />

� Use <strong>of</strong> environmentally sound production technology; and<br />

� Reduction in the energy consumption <strong>of</strong> products and facilities.<br />

However, no evaluation report is available on the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the WEEE MBO on<br />

the prevention <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

15.5.8.2 Environmental Benefits Recycling<br />

In 2007, 55,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> WEEE were collected in Flanders, an increase <strong>of</strong> 10%<br />

compared to 2006. Per capita, 8.9 kg <strong>of</strong> WEEE was collected, exceeding both the<br />

European target <strong>of</strong> 4 kg/capita, and the higher Flemish collection target <strong>of</strong> 8.5<br />

kg/capita.<br />

302 FEBELAUTO (2007) Annual Report.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


RECUPEL has more than 3,600 collection points in Belgium. In addition to CA sites<br />

(container parks), used-good centres and retailers, there are specific collection<br />

channels for gas discharge lamps, medical devices and laboratory equipment (see<br />

Figure 15-5).<br />

In Flanders, approximately 41% <strong>of</strong> the electrical and electronic equipment that is put<br />

on the market is collected as WEEE by RECUPEL.<br />

Figure 15-5: Collection System <strong>of</strong> RECUPEL in Belgium (Annual report 2007,<br />

RECUPEL)<br />

Source: RECUPEL (2007), Annual report<br />

Most <strong>of</strong> the WEEE is collected via the CA sites (30,600 tonnes). The used-good<br />

centres account for 5,700 tonnes. The large household appliances, however, are<br />

collected mainly via retail (where take-back is free if a new appliance is being<br />

purchased).<br />

284<br />

29/09/09


RECUPEL has continually sampled 5 % <strong>of</strong> the collected WEEE for a number <strong>of</strong> years.<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> this detailed sampling is to expose the relationships between the various<br />

product groups in the mixed WEEE streams. It also represents the basis for reporting<br />

to the authorities. The sampling is audited annually by an external party. In 2007<br />

RECUPEL developed an automated sampling machine. Upon arrival <strong>of</strong> the WEEE at<br />

processing sites, the full box pallets are manually emptied and sorted. Each appliance<br />

then passes by on a conveyor belt, whereby the operator indicates by means <strong>of</strong> a<br />

touch screen to which WEEE category the appliance belongs. At the same time the<br />

appliance is weighed and photographed, which allows for subsequent checks.<br />

Automation therefore implies improvement in efficiency compared to the earlier,<br />

manual sampling method. RECUPEL entrust WEEE sampling completely to the<br />

sheltered social workshops Revam (Flanders) and Hautes Ardennes (Wallonia). The<br />

RECUPEL sampling machine is also gaining support outside <strong>of</strong> Belgium. 303<br />

Table 15-6 presents the recycling and recovery percentages <strong>of</strong> the different types <strong>of</strong><br />

WEEE in Flanders. 304<br />

Table 15-6 Recycling and Recovery Percentages <strong>of</strong> WEEE in Flanders<br />

Type Type <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> WEEE WEEE<br />

Target<br />

Target<br />

Result Results Result<br />

(VLAREA)<br />

(VLAREA)<br />

(Recupel)<br />

(Recupel)<br />

Large white<br />

goods<br />

Total Reuse and recycling 80% 82.91%<br />

Total Recovery 85% 82.44%<br />

Ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Non-ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Synthetic<br />

materials<br />

Reuse and recycling 50% 73.04%<br />

Synthetic Recovery 80% 75.64%<br />

Cooling and<br />

freezing<br />

appliances<br />

Total Reuse and recycling 80% 79.70%<br />

Total Recovery 85% 93.80%<br />

Ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Non-ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Synthetic Reuse and recycling 50% 33.47%<br />

Synthetic Recovery 80% 90.61%<br />

Television<br />

screens and<br />

monitors<br />

Total Reuse and recycling 70% 86.92%<br />

Total Recovery 75% 89.09%<br />

Ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Non-ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Synthetic Reuse and recycling 50% 71.23%<br />

Synthetic Recovery 80% 82.25%<br />

Other<br />

appliances<br />

Total Reuse and recycling 70% 81.17%<br />

Total Recovery 75% 82.03%<br />

303 RECUPEL (2007) Annual Report.<br />

304 RECUPEL (2007) Annual Report.<br />

285<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Type Type <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> WEEE WEEE<br />

Target Target<br />

Target<br />

Result Results Result<br />

(VLAREA)<br />

(VLAREA)<br />

(Recupel)<br />

(Recupel)<br />

Ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Non-ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Synthetic Reuse and recycling 50% 85.51%<br />

Synthetic Recovery 80% 97.79%<br />

Gas discharge<br />

lamps<br />

Total Reuse and recycling 80% 96.33%<br />

Total Recovery 95% 100.00%<br />

Ferrous Reuse and recycling 95% 100.00%<br />

Non-ferrous Reuse and recycling<br />

Synthetic Reuse and recycling<br />

Synthetic Recovery<br />

Source: RECUPEL (2007), Annual report<br />

15.5.9 Flash Torches<br />

15.5.9.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

The MBO stipulates the following actions for producers:<br />

286<br />

� Use <strong>of</strong> easy to recycle materials;<br />

� Prevent the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances;<br />

� Use <strong>of</strong> environmentally sound production technology; and<br />

� Reduction in the energy consumption <strong>of</strong> products and facilities.<br />

There is no evaluation report on flash torches available with respect to these actions.<br />

15.5.9.2 Environmental Benefits Recycling<br />

No collection or recycling targets are defined yet. According to OVAM, they should be<br />

implemented with the revision <strong>of</strong> VLAREA by June 2009 at the latest.<br />

15.5.10 Used Oil<br />

15.5.10.1 Environmental Benefits <strong>of</strong> Prevention<br />

Every year, VALORLUB draws up a prevention plan. The MBO stipulates that producers<br />

and importers (through VALORLUB) must inform and sensitise consumers on the<br />

proper and economical use <strong>of</strong> oil.<br />

The article on prevention in the MBO, however, focuses more on proper and safe<br />

collection and disposal <strong>of</strong> used oil (qualitative prevention) rather than on quantitative<br />

prevention (reduction <strong>of</strong> the quantities <strong>of</strong> used oil).<br />

15.5.10.2 Environmental Benefits <strong>of</strong> Recycling<br />

The percentage <strong>of</strong> collection that has to be obtained amounts to 100% <strong>of</strong> all the<br />

collectable used oil. The percentages <strong>of</strong> useful use that have to be obtained are at<br />

least 85% recycling and maximum 15% energy recovery.<br />

The achieved recycling percentage amounts to 95%. The collection percentage is not<br />

clear yet. First, the total amount <strong>of</strong> collectable used oil needs to be identified. A study<br />

29/09/09


is currently being performed to identify this amount. According to VALORLUB, a<br />

collection percentage <strong>of</strong> almost 100% will probably be achievable. 305<br />

15.5.11 Animal and Vegetable Fats and Oils<br />

15.5.11.1 Environmental Benefits Prevention<br />

The MBO stipulates no specific actions with regard to prevention.<br />

15.5.11.2 Environmental Benefits Recycling<br />

The MBO obligates a collection percentage <strong>of</strong> at least 95% <strong>of</strong> collectable waste oil. In<br />

2007, a collection percentage <strong>of</strong> only 40% <strong>of</strong> collectable oil was achieved. Mainly the<br />

oil used by households seems ‘to get lost’. 306<br />

In 2007, about 28,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> domestic oil was put on the market. It was analysed<br />

that about 76% <strong>of</strong> this oil generates waste oil. This would mean that about 21,000<br />

ton <strong>of</strong> domestic oil should have been collected. In reality, only 8,000 tonnes were<br />

collected! Surveys suggested that about 78% <strong>of</strong> the people claim to hand in their<br />

domestic oil. VALORFRIT will perform a new study to investigate the differences. 307<br />

In 2007, about 35,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> commercial oil were put on the market. was<br />

Analysis suggested that about 60% <strong>of</strong> this oil generates waste oil. This would mean<br />

that about 21,000 ton <strong>of</strong> domestic oil should have been collected. In reality, 18,000<br />

tonnes were collected. 308<br />

As a collection percentage <strong>of</strong> 95% seems difficult to get to, the target will be reduced<br />

in the new VLAREA. An annex with the new target will soon be published.<br />

Due to the high residual value <strong>of</strong> waste animal and vegetable oil, 100% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

collected oil is recovered. In 2007, 63% was converted into biodiesel, 14% was<br />

recovered in plastics, industrial soap, lubricants, etc, and 19% was incinerated with<br />

energy recovery. 309 No targets for the different treatment options were stipulated in<br />

the MBO, since a LCA study performed by VITO showed no significant difference with<br />

regard to environmental performance. 310<br />

15.6 Implementation Costs<br />

The nature <strong>of</strong> the policy means that costs are to be carried by the producers subject<br />

to EPR. Costs can be split up into:<br />

305 Frank Vanderpooten, personal communication.<br />

306 Tom Smidts, VALORFRIT, personal communication.<br />

307 Tom Smidts, VALORFRIT, personal communication.<br />

308 Tom Smidts, VALORFRIT, personal communication.<br />

309 www.valorfrit.be<br />

310 K. Briffaerts, F. Sleeuwaert, I.Vanderreydt, K. Vrancken (2008) Vergelijkende levenscyclusanalyse<br />

van toepassingen van dierlijk vet en gebruikte frituurvetten en oliën (Comparative Life Cycle Analysis<br />

Of Uses Of Animal Fats And Used Frying Fats And Oils), Dutch, VITO, 2008.<br />

287<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


288<br />

� Financing the data collection. Several industry bodies buy data on collected<br />

amounts <strong>of</strong> a specific waste from the waste collectors;<br />

� Financing the awareness raising and creating incentives for sorting the waste<br />

into selective waste streams by the producer;<br />

� Financing the waste collection. In the cases where municipal infrastructure is<br />

used, it is considered important to take care that no public resources are used<br />

to serve a private company or to fulfil the EPR obligations imposed on<br />

industrial sectors. For example, a Flemish Ministerial Decree <strong>of</strong> 2005 sets in<br />

place the calculation <strong>of</strong> the collection costs on a standardised civic amenity<br />

site and points out how industry bodies have to remunerate the civic amenity<br />

sites for the collection <strong>of</strong> the EPR-waste.<br />

The traditional relationship between waste producer and waste collector is broken as<br />

there is no cost implication at the point <strong>of</strong> waste generation. Rather, this cost is<br />

included at the product purchase stage. The industry body <strong>of</strong> an EPR-scheme will<br />

determine who will collect the waste. Costs borne by collectors are reimbursed by the<br />

management body – which in turn is funded by producers. Of course, this is likely to<br />

be reflected in product prices, but it does ensure that the full costs <strong>of</strong> a product life<br />

cycle are incorporated in purchase costs.<br />

15.6.1 Packaging <strong>Waste</strong><br />

FOST-Plus pays the intermunicipalities the full cost <strong>of</strong> collection and sorting as well as<br />

paying for communication with residents, follow up and quality-based bonuses. In the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> services being provided by the intermunicipality, the price is based on average<br />

cost. In 2007, the operating costs <strong>of</strong> FOST-Plus amounted to €138 million. 311<br />

FOST-Plus operating income in 2007 amounted to €119.7 million, which represents a<br />

4.6% increase from 2006 (€ 114.5 million). This rise can be totally ascribed to the<br />

increase in proceeds from materials. The value <strong>of</strong> all materials increased from<br />

€32.1m to €41.0 m in 2007. The members’ contributions (Green dot fees) were<br />

therefore lowered from € 82.4 to €78.74 million (see Table 15-7 and Figure 15-6).<br />

The combination <strong>of</strong> the total costs <strong>of</strong> €138 million, the operational income <strong>of</strong> €119.7<br />

million and additional income <strong>of</strong> €25.36 million led to a net surplus <strong>of</strong> income over<br />

expenditure <strong>of</strong> €7.148 m in 2007.<br />

311 Fost Plus (2007) Annual Report.<br />

29/09/09


Table 15-7 Green Dot Fees for Packaging (Annual report FOST-Plus, 2007)<br />

Source: Fost Plus (2007), Annual Report<br />

Table 15-8 Fees for Commercial Packaging<br />

Single use packaging<br />

Paper, cardboard, metals, glass,<br />

recyclable natural fibres, wood,<br />

other recyclable materials<br />

289<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Financing Financing contribution contribution in in €/ton<br />

2007 2008<br />

14.50 13.00<br />

Recyclable plastics 39.50 35.50<br />

Non recyclable materials 43,50 43.50<br />

Reusable packaging<br />

Recyclable plastics for the<br />

construction industry<br />

Source: VAL-I-PAC (2008), IMPACT nr 3, January 2008 newsletter<br />

35.50 40.50


Figure 15-6: Earnings from Green Dot Fees and Recyclates Sales, Fost Plus<br />

15.6.2 Printed Material<br />

‘Publishers’ <strong>of</strong> publicity and unsolicited mail pay a contribution <strong>of</strong> €0.005 per kg<br />

paper they put on the market. These contributions are used to reimburse<br />

(inter)municipalities for their waste paper collection (container parks and door-to-door<br />

collection).<br />

‘Publishers’ <strong>of</strong> periodical press reserve advertisement space worth €3 million per year<br />

for the Flemish government. As mentioned above, the government uses this space<br />

mainly for advertisements on prevention or recycling.<br />

15.6.3 <strong>Waste</strong> Batteries<br />

Companies pay an annual fee <strong>of</strong> €60 to BEBAT, which covers the operational costs <strong>of</strong><br />

BEBAT. In addition, a fee <strong>of</strong> €0.1239 per battery is paid by the producers to finance<br />

the collection and recovery/disposal <strong>of</strong> the waste batteries. This fee is passed on to<br />

the consumers. In 2007, total income through these contributions amounted up to<br />

€19 million. 312<br />

The contribution from the consumers, however, exceeds the costs for collection and<br />

recovery/disposal by 30%. In 2007, the costs <strong>of</strong> operating BEBAT amounted up to<br />

€12.7 million.<br />

312 BEBAT (2007) Annual Report.<br />

290<br />

29/09/09<br />

Green Dot Sales <strong>of</strong> recyclate


Moreover, the provisions <strong>of</strong> BEBAT now amount to more than €37 million.<br />

According to OVAM, these high provisions show that the contribution per battery is set<br />

too high. As the contribution is determined at federal level (through ecotax<br />

legislation), OVAM has no say in a possible reduction <strong>of</strong> the contribution.<br />

15.6.4 <strong>Waste</strong> Accumulators<br />

Companies pay an annual fee <strong>of</strong> €100 and €0.08 per battery to RECYBAT. In 2007,<br />

total income <strong>of</strong> RECYBAT amounted to about €68,000. Operational costs <strong>of</strong> RECYBAT<br />

amounted to €38,500 (no collection system had to be put in place). 313<br />

15.6.5 Old and Expired Medication<br />

Almost 2,600 chemists participate in the collection <strong>of</strong> old and expired medication.<br />

Nine wholesalers coordinate the collection and transport <strong>of</strong> the medication to the<br />

incineration plants. The 111 members <strong>of</strong> AVGI and FEBELGEN finance the<br />

incineration <strong>of</strong> the medication. 314<br />

In 2007, 23,395 special boxes were used for the collection <strong>of</strong> waste medication in<br />

Flanders, representing about 300,000 kg (around 50 gram/capita). The costs for<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> these boxes amounted to €68,313. The costs for incineration amounted<br />

to €99,556. Since 1996, the amount <strong>of</strong> collected waste medication has remained at<br />

similar levels.<br />

15.6.6 End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

Members <strong>of</strong> FEBELAUTO pay an annual contribution. These contributions are used to<br />

finance the operational costs <strong>of</strong> FEBELAUTO. Due to the relatively high residual value<br />

<strong>of</strong> end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles, no contributions are necessary to finance the recovery and<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> the vehicles. In 2007, the turnover amounted to €344,000.<br />

15.6.7 <strong>Waste</strong> Tyres<br />

The financing <strong>of</strong> the take-back system for tyres is paid by the consumer. He or she<br />

pays a fee per tyre, depending on its type and size; e.g. €2.4 per tyre for cars, €12.46<br />

for lorries and buses. In 2007, RECYTYRE had an operating income <strong>of</strong> more than €17<br />

million (almost 80 ktonnes waste tyres). 315 Among other charges, RECYTYRE<br />

compensates the operators for the collection and recovery/disposal <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

tyres (more than €14 million) and the 435 CA sites that accept waste tyres from<br />

private sources (€ 173,000).<br />

313 RECYBAT (2007) Annual Report.<br />

314 OVAM (2008) Oude en vervallen geneesmiddelen – Inzamelresultaten 2007 (Old and expired<br />

medication – Collection data 2007), Dutch.<br />

315 RECYTYRE (2007) Annual Report.<br />

291<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


15.6.8 <strong>Waste</strong> from Electrical and Electronic Equipment<br />

Manufacturers and importers pay a recycling contribution when bringing products<br />

onto the Belgian market. These contributions are paid to, and are managed by, the<br />

sector associations.<br />

For certain products, an all-in contribution is charged. This is the case for all domestic<br />

categories <strong>of</strong> the existing 7 sectors as well as all medical devices and laboratory<br />

equipment, and all lighting devices. This all-in contribution is used to finance the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> the collection, transport, sorting and treatment <strong>of</strong> the discarded appliances<br />

that are taken back to the store or the container park. A part <strong>of</strong> this contribution is<br />

used to finance the coordination and communication by RECUPEL (administration,<br />

reporting, audits). The all-in contribution ranges from €0.5 for small household<br />

appliances to €1 for freezers and refrigerators (www.recupel.be, English version).<br />

For certain products only, an administrative contribution is charged when the product<br />

is put on the Belgian market. This is the case for all pr<strong>of</strong>essional appliances (other<br />

than household), including monitoring and control appliances. This administrative<br />

contribution is used to cover reporting and administrative costs. The costs for the<br />

transport and treatment <strong>of</strong> the appliances is calculated when the discarded product is<br />

delivered to the treatment partners. The administrative contribution ranges from<br />

€0.05 for fittings for gas discharge lamps to €1.5 for pr<strong>of</strong>essional laboratory<br />

equipment (www.recupel.be, English version).<br />

In 2007, total income <strong>of</strong> RECUPEL amounted up to €28.5 million. About €27.8 million<br />

was spent to remunerate municipalities and operators for the collection and<br />

recovery/disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE.<br />

15.6.9 Flash Torches<br />

Producers and importers <strong>of</strong> flash torches pay an annual contribution <strong>of</strong> €60 and a<br />

contribution <strong>of</strong> €0.20 per flash torch put onto the Belgian market. This contribution is<br />

passed on to the consumers.<br />

No data on the operational costs <strong>of</strong> BEBAT are publicly available.<br />

15.6.10 Used Oil<br />

VALORLUB pays the costs for the collection and the processing <strong>of</strong> used oil in<br />

container parks, companies, etc. VALORLUB also has to obtain the objectives laid<br />

down by the legislator (maximal collection, priority to regeneration and reuse).<br />

To finance this, the producers and importers <strong>of</strong> oil pay an annual contribution to<br />

Valorlub. This contribution depends on the quantities and the type <strong>of</strong> oil that they<br />

bring into the market (VAT (21%) excluded):<br />

292<br />

� Annual contribution: €150 the first year <strong>of</strong> membership; €150 for the following<br />

years <strong>of</strong> membership;<br />

� Contribution per litre <strong>of</strong> oil brought into the Belgian market or oil imported for<br />

own use:<br />

29/09/09<br />

• Domestic oil (= engine oil in packs <strong>of</strong> up to and including 25 kg): €0,28<br />

per litre;


293<br />

• All other types <strong>of</strong> oil generating waste oil: €0,02 per litre.<br />

No data on the operational costs <strong>of</strong> VALORLUB are available yet. The first annual<br />

report is expected by June 2009 (VALORLUB has only recently been operational).<br />

15.6.11 Animal and Vegetable Fats and Oils<br />

Producers and importers <strong>of</strong> oil pay a contribution to VALORFRIT, depending on the<br />

quantities and the type <strong>of</strong> oil that they bring into the market:<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Fat Fat<br />

Oil<br />

Domestic rate ≤ 2.5 kg: €0.030/kg ≤ 3 l: 0.0276/l<br />

Commercial rate > 2.5 kg: €0.030/kg > 3 l: 0.00828/l<br />

For some larger companies, the yearly contribution amounts to €750,000. This<br />

contribution is usually passed on to the consumers.<br />

In 2007, VALORFRIT had an operating income <strong>of</strong> almost €2 million (Annual report<br />

2007, VALORFRIT).<br />

In 2007, the charges <strong>of</strong> VALORFRIT (€2 million) were composed <strong>of</strong> the<br />

reimbursements <strong>of</strong> the operators for the collection and recovery/disposal <strong>of</strong> the<br />

waste oil (more than €95,000), the reimbursement <strong>of</strong> the municipalities for the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> domestic oil via their container parks (€ 380,000), communication and<br />

sensitization costs (€1 million) and the operational costs <strong>of</strong> VALORFRIT<br />

(€460,000). 316<br />

The monetary reserve <strong>of</strong> VALORFRIT amounted to €2.7 million in 2007 and will be<br />

systematically diminished in the period 2008-2012 in accordance with the<br />

management plan for the period.<br />

15.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

OECD remarked in its study on extended producer responsibility that EPR really did<br />

have an impact on the amount <strong>of</strong> waste collected for recycling, but that the relation<br />

with prevention and design-for-environment is hard to prove: “it is hard to know<br />

whether firms made the changes in response to the policies or for cost-savings or<br />

other reasons.” 317 EPR schemes <strong>of</strong>ten tend to evolve from a prevention incentive<br />

towards a funding scheme for recycling.<br />

In Flanders most EPR schemes operate with overall goals to be achieved by an entire<br />

sector, and only limited goals to be achieved by individual participants <strong>of</strong> the system.<br />

316 VALORFRIT (2008) Annual Report 2007.<br />

317 OECD working group WGWPR, EPR Policies and Product Design: Economic Theory and Selected<br />

Case Studies, 2006.


This affects the incentive that the EPR could have on promoting ecodesign within<br />

individual companies. This is because <strong>of</strong> what are effectively free-rider effects<br />

associated with the effects <strong>of</strong> the activities <strong>of</strong> individual producers.<br />

15.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

Households and private consumers are charged an EPR contribution when buying<br />

electrical <strong>of</strong> electronic equipment or other EPR goods. The Flemish legislation<br />

requires that the part <strong>of</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong> the EPR that is charged to the consumer should<br />

be clearly visible on the sales invoice. In respect <strong>of</strong> comparable products this raises<br />

awareness on the environmental impact associated with a product.<br />

However, the analysis in Section 15.6 suggests that the costs <strong>of</strong> EPR are a minimal<br />

part <strong>of</strong> the price <strong>of</strong> products. As such, although the approach is, by its nature,<br />

regressive, the effects on prices are not significant. Indeed, as discussed in the pay<br />

by use section for Flanders, the costs <strong>of</strong> all producer responsibility schemes are<br />

reflected in a net cost <strong>of</strong> around 36 Euros per year for each household on average.<br />

This is unlikely to have a major social impact.<br />

15.9 Complementary Policies<br />

Since an EPR combines a take-back obligation with recycling targets, accompanying<br />

policies might be necessary to create enough recycling capacity. The dynamics <strong>of</strong> the<br />

free market ought to open up recycling capacity when the demand for capacity<br />

increases. It is however necessary to ensure that the recycling capacity is sustainable.<br />

Export <strong>of</strong> EPR goods like paper or WEEE to non-OECD countries for recycling needs to<br />

be monitored and the quality <strong>of</strong> the recycling technology needs to be assured.<br />

Communication efforts on the collection <strong>of</strong> a specific waste, paid for by the industry<br />

bodies, can be completed with more general awareness raising activities by the public<br />

authorities.<br />

Compliance with EPR objectives is assessed on the basis <strong>of</strong> the data provided by the<br />

producers themselves, which originates from the industry bodies. It is important for<br />

the competent authorities to compare the reported data with an independent and<br />

neutral data source to evaluate the credibility <strong>of</strong> this data.<br />

15.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

Where the strongest influence on the management <strong>of</strong> waste (both prior to and at the<br />

point <strong>of</strong> production) was previously held by the waste collectors (who operate on a<br />

competitive basis and so may be expected to provide lower quality services), the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> EPR policies shifted this market influence to the producers <strong>of</strong><br />

products. The EPR policies create industry bodies <strong>of</strong> a more monopolistic nature. In<br />

Belgium the cost structures <strong>of</strong> these industry bodies do not need to be made public in<br />

a financial report. The cost structure is therefore not transparent, which gives rise to<br />

controversies about whether the Belgian solution is more expensive in comparison<br />

with other international approaches.<br />

On the other hand, the government has a larger possible impact on a centralised body<br />

on which it can impose concrete and specific conditions through its notification<br />

294<br />

29/09/09


procedure. It would be considerably more difficult to manage several different waste<br />

collectors though their individual permits.<br />

15.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

MBOs are signed with representative industry associations which do not always cover<br />

the full 100% <strong>of</strong> the market. Industry bodies are established but companies are free<br />

to join these bodies or to fulfil their EPR-obligations on their own. In practice, a certain<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> producers neither join the EPR bodies nor fulfil EPR obligations on their<br />

own. They are called ‘free-riders’ because they pr<strong>of</strong>it from the advantages <strong>of</strong> the MBO<br />

(e.g. they are not subject to extra legislation) while they do not contribute to the<br />

efforts <strong>of</strong> the MBO. In the Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> Agreements, eliminating free-riders is<br />

explicitly included as an important responsibility for the signing authority.<br />

A specific service within OVAM, containing 15 employees, has been established with<br />

the explicit task to enforce the EPR and to identify free-riders. Within the IVCIE, five<br />

employees are involved in enforcement on packaging waste free-riders.<br />

Households are also obliged to use the correct collection channels for obligated<br />

materials. Figure 15-7shows an example <strong>of</strong> measures taken to enforce compliance.<br />

Figure 15-7: Sticker Used by FOST Plus to Warn the Householder <strong>of</strong> Wrong Content<br />

15.12 Lessons Learned<br />

EPR mechanisms do not always lead to better environmental design, but are very<br />

effective in enhancing the amount <strong>of</strong> waste collected for recycling.<br />

When EPR-targets are imposed in a rather large industry group, e.g. the producers <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging waste, the incentive for individual companies to change their packaging<br />

strategy can become watered down. When easy to recycle packaging is collected in<br />

sufficient amounts, the recycling targets <strong>of</strong> the sector can be reached and the<br />

producers <strong>of</strong> difficult to recycle packaging can pr<strong>of</strong>it from the results <strong>of</strong> the sector as<br />

a whole without being incentivised to develop more recyclable packaging waste<br />

themselves. In Belgium, companies contributing to FOST-Plus (the industry body for<br />

household packaging waste) receive a green dot label. But the FOST-Plus collection<br />

scheme for packaging is selective in the kind <strong>of</strong> packaging waste that is collected.<br />

Difficult or expensive to recycle waste, such as butter packaging, is excluded from the<br />

295<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


collection, although they have a green dot and contribute to the system. The costs for<br />

recycling are not increasing and, with the policy structured in this way, companies like<br />

Alpro do not have an incentive to revise their packaging strategy.<br />

To be cost effective EPR industry bodies must work in full transparency and should be<br />

prevented from applying a monopolistic approach to the waste collection market<br />

(collection costs are expected to be minimised in a competitive market where bidding<br />

for the collection contract occurs).<br />

Data is <strong>of</strong>ten purchased by the industry bodies from the waste collectors. This could<br />

lead to bias, when the waste collector sells what the industry body wants to receive.<br />

Unbiased information on waste generation and collection (via independent sources <strong>of</strong><br />

data or independent auditing) is necessary to check the reliability <strong>of</strong> the compliance<br />

reports <strong>of</strong> the industry bodies.<br />

15.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

An important element in the establishment <strong>of</strong> EPR-policies is the political will to go<br />

further than the EPR imposed by the European Recycling Directives. In Flanders EPR<br />

policies on wood waste, agricultural foil and floor coverings have been removed from<br />

the legislation, even before they entered into force, due to changing political will.<br />

Industry support is not easy to obtain, and both the waste collection industry and the<br />

involved production industry may oppose an EPR except where this is accompanied<br />

by strong legislation.<br />

EPR policies require manpower and administrative tools both for inspections relating<br />

to free-riders and for data gathering.<br />

296<br />

29/09/09


16.0 Deposit Refund Systems - <strong>International</strong><br />

16.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

“A deposit-refund system is the surcharge on the price <strong>of</strong> potentially polluting<br />

products. When pollution is avoided by returning the products or their residuals, a<br />

refund <strong>of</strong> the surcharge is granted.” OECD, Glossary <strong>of</strong> Statistical Terms. 318<br />

A deposit refund system encourages the return <strong>of</strong> the materials into an organized<br />

recycling or reuse process. The producers can finance that process through a fraction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the deposit, or to ensure that the deposit paid is the same as that received, those<br />

subject to the deposit scheme can pay a separate payment for the administration <strong>of</strong><br />

the scheme.<br />

Drinks containers are the most common target <strong>of</strong> deposit refund systems, though<br />

economic theory suggests that the schemes could be applicable to hazardous<br />

materials and other waste streams, subject to transaction costs being minimised (see<br />

Annex 2.0). The systems can encourage recycling and / or reuse where otherwise it is<br />

easy to dispose <strong>of</strong> containers with the residual waste. The same policy mechanism<br />

can also be used to target difficult to dispose <strong>of</strong>, or hazardous, items to ensure that<br />

these do not reach the residual waste stream. This can be considered a waste<br />

prevention policy as it reduces the hazardousness <strong>of</strong> materials in the waste stream.<br />

Non-drinks container examples include:<br />

297<br />

� Batteries (Swedish Östhammar example) and car batteries (Germany); 319 and<br />

� Tyres (Maine, USA).<br />

Finally, some countries, e.g. Sweden make use <strong>of</strong> vehicle scrapping charges, which<br />

discourages the dumping <strong>of</strong> vehicle bodies in rural areas and ensures that cars are<br />

returned to registered scrapping destinations at the end <strong>of</strong> their life. 320<br />

16.2 Economic Rationale for Deposit Refund Schemes<br />

Deposit refund schemes are a particular form <strong>of</strong> product tax/recycling subsidy. In<br />

such programmes, also known as ‘bottle bill’ programmes, consumers pay a deposit<br />

(tax) on a container at the time <strong>of</strong> purchase. This should, in theory, be set at the extra<br />

social cost <strong>of</strong> improper disposal over the net recycling cost (assuming there is already<br />

an Advance Disposal Fee (ADF) on the manufacturer equal to the net recycling cost).<br />

This means that if the product is improperly disposed <strong>of</strong>, that individual pays the<br />

318 http://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=594<br />

319 http://www.eeb.org/activities/waste/EEB-mini-brief-deposit-schemes-for-Batteries-March2004.pdf<br />

320 The (sometimes temporary) scrapping charges which have become popular across nations in the<br />

context <strong>of</strong> the current economic decline have their precedent in the more permanent schemes which<br />

some countries employ to ensure that end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles are returned to an appropriate recycler.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


external cost <strong>of</strong> improper disposal by foregoing the refund, which would typically be<br />

set equal to the initial deposit.<br />

This incentive is considered particularly appropriate for items with hazardous<br />

contents where it is important to keep them out <strong>of</strong> landfills or incinerators, as well as<br />

to discourage their illegal dumping. Likewise for products where the temptation to<br />

litter is high, or the resulting litter is considered to create significant disamenity<br />

impacts, mandatory deposits may be imposed.<br />

The distinction between deposit refund schemes on the one hand, and ADFs coupled<br />

with a household recycling refund on the other, is in the re-collection <strong>of</strong> the product at<br />

the end <strong>of</strong> its useful life. Mandatory deposit schemes involve a separate collection<br />

path, rather than being collected as part <strong>of</strong> the municipal recycling system.<br />

Several theoretical studies have argued that a deposit/refund is the best policy in the<br />

presence <strong>of</strong> illegal disposal. 321 Palmer et al model paper, glass, plastic, aluminium,<br />

and steel. They find a substantial difference in the intervention levels necessary to<br />

achieve reductions in disposal with the various policies. A $45/ton deposit /refund<br />

would reduce all wastes by 10%. Alternatively, the government could obtain a<br />

comparable reduction using an ADF <strong>of</strong> $85/ton or a recycling subsidy <strong>of</strong> $98/ton.<br />

A key point is that the deposit/refund creates incentives for both recycling and source<br />

reduction, whereas an ADF or a recycling subsidy takes advantage <strong>of</strong> only recycling or<br />

source reduction in isolation. 322 However, it is important to note that the theoretical<br />

studies, in abstracting from the real world situation, have not taken into account all<br />

the potential costs <strong>of</strong> administering such schemes. In fact they are not precisely<br />

modelling existing ‘bottle bill’ programmes, but rather a more generalised version <strong>of</strong><br />

deposits and refunds, applied ‘upstream’ on manufacturers and recyclers.<br />

Palmer and Walls accept that in practice there could be significant administrative<br />

costs associated with refunding deposits, which could reduce the efficiency <strong>of</strong> the<br />

approach. 323 This issue is discussed by Palmer et al with numerical estimates <strong>of</strong> the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> administrative costs on the overall efficiency <strong>of</strong> deposit refunds relative to<br />

product taxes and recycling subsidies. 324 Viewing their results alongside empirical<br />

evidence from Ackerman et al., they suggest that administrative costs may be <strong>of</strong> the<br />

321 T. Dinan (1993) Economic Efficiency Effects <strong>of</strong> Alternative Policies for Reducing <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal,<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Environmental Economics and <strong>Management</strong> 25: 242–56; D. Fullerton and T. C. Kinnemann<br />

(1995), Garbage Recycling and Illicit Burning or Dumping, Journal <strong>of</strong> Environmental Economics and<br />

<strong>Management</strong>, 29 (1); Peter S. Menell (1990) Beyond the Throwaway Society: An Incentive Approach to<br />

Regulating Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong>, Ecology Law Quarterly, vol. 17, pp. 655-739; Hilary Sigman (1995) A<br />

Comparison <strong>of</strong> Public Policies for Lead Recycling, RAND Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, vol. 26, no. 3 (Autumn),<br />

pp. 452-478.<br />

322 K. Palmer, H. Sigman and M. Walls (1997) The Cost <strong>of</strong> Reducing Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong>, Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental Economics and <strong>Management</strong> 33, 128-50.<br />

323 Palmer and Walls (1997) Optimal Policies for Solid <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Taxes, Subsidies and Standards.<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> Public Economics 65(8): 193-205.<br />

324 K. Palmer, H. Sigman and M. Walls (1997) The Cost <strong>of</strong> Reducing Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong>, Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental Economics and <strong>Management</strong> 33, 128-50.<br />

298<br />

29/09/09


same order as the cost savings from using a deposit/refund. 325 Due to such<br />

considerations, Palmer et al., Fullerton and Kinnaman, and Palmer and Walls all<br />

argue that deposit refunds should be imposed upstream on producers rather than on<br />

final consumers to minimize administration and transaction costs. 326<br />

The question <strong>of</strong> administrative costs <strong>of</strong> such schemes is a focus <strong>of</strong> much debate<br />

between supporters and opponents <strong>of</strong> such schemes, However, the debate is one<br />

that is unfortunately – on the basis <strong>of</strong> our attempt to elicit such evidence - largely<br />

uninformed by impartial evidence <strong>of</strong> scheme costs.<br />

16.3 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> jurisdictions where deposit refund schemes have been<br />

applied. Table 16-1 shows a list <strong>of</strong> these. In the following sub-sections, we give a<br />

flavour <strong>of</strong> the schemes which have been implemented in different countries.<br />

16.3.1 Denmark<br />

The “Danish Bottle Bill” was passed in 2002, and set up the Dansk Retursystem A/S<br />

to implement and administer the deposit-refund system for beverage containers. The<br />

following deposits apply:<br />

299<br />

� Beverage containers up to 1 litre: €0.13;<br />

� Plastic containers 0.5 litre: €0.27; and<br />

� Beverage containers > 1 litre: €0.40.<br />

When a producer or importer sells beverages to retailers in Denmark, the deposit is<br />

added to the price <strong>of</strong> containers.<br />

The total deposit collected by the producers and importers is paid to Dansk<br />

Retursystem. That deposit cost is passed onto the consumer by the retailer and then<br />

the consumer returns the container either manually or via a reverse vending machine<br />

to the retailer. The containers are then transported to Dansk Retursystem’s collection<br />

centres where they are registered and counted and on the basis <strong>of</strong> this the company<br />

pays the refund back to the retailers.<br />

Essentially, even prior to the Danish Bottle Bill, deposit refund systems had been in<br />

place for decades for refillable containers. Until 2002, domestically produced beer<br />

and s<strong>of</strong>t drinks were only sold in reusable glass, and plastic bottles with a deposit,<br />

whilst sales in cans were prohibited. In 2002, the law was changed, allowing all beer<br />

and carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks to be sold in one-way packaging, including metal cans. It<br />

was this change that prompted the introduction <strong>of</strong> the Bottle Bill.<br />

325 Frank Ackerman, Dmitri Cavander, John Stutz, and Brian Zuckerman (1995) Preliminary Analysis:<br />

The Costs and Benefits <strong>of</strong> Bottle Bills, Draft report to U.S. EPA/Office <strong>of</strong> Solid <strong>Waste</strong> and Emergency<br />

Response, Boston, Mass.: Tellus Institute.<br />

326 D. Fullerton and T. C. Kinnemann (1995), Garbage Recycling and Illicit Burning or Dumping, Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Environmental Economics and <strong>Management</strong>, 29 (1); Palmer et al (1997); Palmer and Walls (1997).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 16-1: Experience with Deposit Refund Schemes in Other Countries / States<br />

Country Country System System<br />

Year Year Year <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Intro Intro Containers Containers Covered Covered Capture<br />

Capture<br />

Rate*<br />

Rate*<br />

Austria Law to make deposit 1992 PET bottles (non-refillables 30% PET<br />

regulatory<br />

excluded)<br />

60% Cans<br />

Belgium<br />

Ecotaxes<br />

Act <strong>of</strong> 1993<br />

300<br />

Containers taxed $0.52<br />

per litre unless they have<br />

deposit.<br />

Croatia Deposit-return plus<br />

‘incentive fee’ to be paid<br />

by producer if 50% refill<br />

isn’t met (5% paid still, if<br />

Denmark<br />

29/09/09<br />

target is met).<br />

Packaging Law. All beer<br />

and s<strong>of</strong>t drinks must be<br />

sold in refillable bottles.<br />

Metal banned until 2002.<br />

Regulatory deposit for<br />

imported glass/plastic<br />

containers. Ecotax also.<br />

1993 Beer, soda and s<strong>of</strong>t drinks<br />

containers<br />

2005 Glass, PET and metal<br />

containers for beer, s<strong>of</strong>t<br />

drinks, water, wine and<br />

spirits.<br />

1989<br />

(amended<br />

1991)<br />

Beer and s<strong>of</strong>t drinks<br />

containers. Deposits on<br />

some wine and spirit<br />

bottles dependent on<br />

retailer.<br />

Estonia Deposit-return 2004 Beer, low alcohol drinks,<br />

carbonated/ noncarbonated<br />

s<strong>of</strong>t drinks,<br />

water, juice, cider and<br />

Finland<br />

Tax on beverage<br />

containers Exemption from<br />

tax only if part <strong>of</strong> refillable<br />

deposit scheme.<br />

Germany Einwegpfand Deposit on<br />

one-way a standard<br />

amount, deposit on<br />

refillables manufacturer<br />

dependent, not legally<br />

specified, though tend to<br />

be similar.<br />

Hungary Tax linked to market share<br />

quotas.<br />

perry.<br />

1970s 1990 One-way beer and s<strong>of</strong>t<br />

drink containers<br />

2003 Not containers for wine,<br />

fruit juice or spirits<br />

2005 Beer, low-alcohol drinks,<br />

wine, mineral water,<br />

carbonated and non-<br />

99.5 %<br />

(beer and<br />

s<strong>of</strong>t drinks<br />

containers<br />

only)<br />

Glass<br />

bottles<br />

99%<br />

Cans 86%<br />

Quota-<br />

Glass 90%<br />

Alu. 90%<br />

Plastic 80%<br />

Quota-<br />

Beer 67%<br />

Low alcohol<br />

Deposit Deposit<br />

Redemption<br />

Redemption<br />

Site<br />

Site<br />

Driver Driver<br />

Reference<br />

Reference<br />

$0.40 Government www.BottleBill.org<br />

$0.12 50cl<br />

$0.27 99cl<br />

Tax $0.14-0.33<br />

Glass 1.0 kroon (refill<br />

and NRB)<br />

Metal and PET < 0.5 l<br />

0.5 kroons PET>0.5l<br />

1kroon<br />

Non-refillables<br />

$0.11<br />

$0.45 for larger sizes<br />

Tax<br />

$0.24 beer $0.47<br />

plastic $0.71 glass<br />

Glass refillable-<br />

Beer € 0.08 S<strong>of</strong>t drink<br />

€ 0.15 (many prices,<br />

not all listed)<br />

Government www.BottleBill.org<br />

Government EUROPEN Report<br />

2007<br />

Government<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

Retailers Government EUROPEN Report<br />

2007<br />

8,000 sites Government<br />

Manufacturers<br />

http://www.ymparisto<br />

.fi/download.asp?con<br />

tentid=16253&lan=E<br />

N<br />

http://www.bookrags.<br />

com/Container_depo<br />

sit_legislation


Country Country System System<br />

Year Year <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Intro Intro Containers Containers Covered Covered Capture<br />

Capture<br />

Rate*<br />

Rate*<br />

carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks. 28% Wine<br />

20%<br />

Iceland Tax on non-refillable 2008 Non-refillable glass, steel,<br />

containers.<br />

aluminium and plastic.<br />

Kiribati Special Fund Act 2004 2004 Aluminium cans and PET<br />

drinks bottles<br />

Malta<br />

Deposit<br />

Return<br />

System<br />

301<br />

Previous ban <strong>of</strong> non-glass<br />

beverage containers, lifted<br />

Mexico Higher tax on non-refillable<br />

bottles and cans.<br />

Fed. States (Deposit-return) 1991 Currently only aluminium<br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

(amended cans, but glass and plastic<br />

Micronesia<br />

2006) expected to be added<br />

Kosrae<br />

Recycling<br />

Program<br />

soon.<br />

Netherland Agreement deposit 1993 S<strong>of</strong>t drinks and water in<br />

s<br />

one-way and refillable<br />

glass and PET containers<br />

Norway<br />

Deposit on containers and<br />

tax dependent on return<br />

rate.<br />

Refillables only exempt if<br />

95% return rate is<br />

achieved. Retailers (on<br />

site >25m²) selling nonrefillables,<br />

must also sell<br />

similar products in<br />

refillable.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

1994 Most drinks excluding milk,<br />

vegetable juices and water<br />

Peru Deposit on some bottles 620ml size beer bottles<br />

Portugal Fillers must ensure quotas<br />

Quotasmet<br />

Beer 80%<br />

Retailers must sell<br />

Wine (with certain<br />

refillables for all non-<br />

exceptions) 65% S<strong>of</strong>t<br />

20,000<br />

cans per<br />

day<br />

Refillable<br />

glass 98%<br />

Refillable<br />

PET 99%<br />

Wine/<br />

spirits 60%<br />

Beer 98%<br />

S<strong>of</strong>t drinks<br />

98%<br />

Deposit Deposit<br />

Redemption<br />

Redemption<br />

Site<br />

Site<br />

$0.05 ($0.04<br />

returned)<br />

Kaoki Mange<br />

operating<br />

centres.<br />

$0.06 ($0.05 back) Kosrae Island<br />

Resource<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Authority<br />

(KIRMA) sites<br />

PET and glass:<br />

$0.16 5l<br />

$0.16 5l (+Tax<br />

inversely proportional<br />

to return rate, but if<br />

above 95%, no tax)<br />

Over 9000<br />

establishments<br />

in the country,<br />

plus 3000<br />

deposit<br />

machines<br />

where receipt is<br />

given<br />

Driver Driver<br />

Reference<br />

Reference<br />

Industry<br />

Tax is<br />

government<br />

driven, but<br />

recycling fee in<br />

place is retailer<br />

driven<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org


Country Country System System<br />

Year Year <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Intro Intro Containers Containers Covered Covered Capture<br />

Capture<br />

Rate*<br />

Rate*<br />

refillables sold. drinks 30%<br />

South Deposit return system, Around Approx. 75% beer, 45%<br />

Africa voluntary i.e. manufacturer 1948 s<strong>of</strong>t drinks and some wine<br />

driven, not Government.<br />

and spirits bottles<br />

Spain Return<br />

overall 87%<br />

Reuse beer<br />

Sweden Law requires rate <strong>of</strong> 90%<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> aluminium<br />

cans, or complete ban.<br />

Industry implemented<br />

deposit system to avoid<br />

this. PET introduced later<br />

as well.<br />

deposit<br />

Switzerland Deposits required on all<br />

refillable drinks containers<br />

except cans, which have a<br />

voluntary tax <strong>of</strong> $0.04.<br />

South<br />

Australia<br />

Canada-<br />

Alberta<br />

302<br />

Container Deposit<br />

Legislation- deposit<br />

required on almost all<br />

drinks containers, with<br />

onus on manufacturer/<br />

wholesaler to ensure<br />

convenient system in<br />

place for deposit <strong>of</strong><br />

container/ refunds for<br />

customers.<br />

All containers sold in<br />

Alberta (including imports)<br />

must be registered<br />

29/09/09<br />

Deposit on<br />

one-way<br />

containers-<br />

1984 for<br />

cans.<br />

1994 for<br />

PET<br />

(refillables<br />

already in<br />

place)<br />

Aluminium cans and PET<br />

law. Deposit now on most<br />

beverage containers.<br />

1990 All above a certain weight<br />

(currently all!)<br />

1975<br />

(integrated<br />

into<br />

Environment<br />

Protection<br />

Act in 1993)<br />

Most included except wine<br />

(unless in plastic bottle),<br />

milk, pure fruit juice or<br />

flavoured milk >1l.<br />

1972 All beverage containers<br />

regulatory except milk,<br />

which is under a voluntary<br />

57%<br />

Recovery<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> 80-<br />

90% on<br />

one way<br />

containers<br />

Refillable<br />

glass 95-<br />

98%<br />

Refillable<br />

PET 70%<br />

85% nonrefillable<br />

glass<br />

84% cans<br />

74% PET<br />

Glass (AB<br />

Beer) 96%<br />

Glass<br />

Deposit Deposit<br />

Redemption<br />

Redemption<br />

Site<br />

Site<br />

Between 8-15% <strong>of</strong><br />

product cost<br />

(or 0.5-1% if<br />

wine/spirit)<br />

Voluntary Cans $0.07<br />

Refillable PET $0.56<br />

One-way PET $0.14-<br />

0.24<br />

Ref. glass $0.166l<br />

Ref and one-way PET<br />

$0.40>1.5l<br />

$0.10 if refillable to<br />

retailer (rare) $0.05 if<br />

refillable to collection<br />

depot (99.9% done<br />

this way)<br />

$0.05 1l Beer $0.10<br />

Mostly<br />

collection<br />

depots, though<br />

some store<br />

refillables.<br />

215<br />

independent<br />

depots and 78<br />

Driver Driver<br />

Reference<br />

Reference<br />

Manufacturer<br />

Law government<br />

driven.<br />

Standard bottle<br />

and deposit<br />

brewer/bottler<br />

driven.<br />

Government<br />

Government<br />

legislation with<br />

manufacturer/<br />

wholesaler<br />

responsibility<br />

Initially<br />

government,<br />

until 1997 when<br />

http://www.cervecero<br />

s.org/<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

http://en.wikipedia.or<br />

g/wiki/Container_dep<br />

osit_legislation<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org


Country Country System System<br />

Year Year <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Intro Intro Containers Containers Covered Covered Capture<br />

Capture<br />

Rate*<br />

Rate*<br />

through the Beverage<br />

scheme<br />

(import<br />

Container <strong>Management</strong><br />

beer) 92%<br />

Board (BCMB).<br />

Alu (beer)<br />

89%<br />

Alu (s<strong>of</strong>t)<br />

79%<br />

Overall<br />

78%<br />

Canada-<br />

British<br />

Columbia<br />

Canada-<br />

Manitoba<br />

Canada-<br />

New<br />

Brunswick<br />

Canada-<br />

Newfoundla<br />

nd<br />

303<br />

All containers must be<br />

refillable, and none<br />

collected can be landfilled<br />

or incinerated.<br />

Beer separate system,<br />

though still under<br />

legislation.<br />

Beverage producers given<br />

option <strong>of</strong> setting up<br />

deposit-return system, or<br />

adding a 2 cent per<br />

container levy. Only beer<br />

producers choose the<br />

former.<br />

Deposits paid on all<br />

containers (bar milk), but<br />

whilst full paid back on<br />

refillables, only half paid<br />

back on non-refillables.<br />

Half-back system, with<br />

manufacturers prohibited<br />

from selling containers<br />

other than recyclable or<br />

refillable for selected<br />

products. Beer operated<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

1970 All beverage containers<br />

except milk, soya milk,<br />

infant formulas, dietary or<br />

meal supplements, or<br />

other milk substitutes.<br />

81.3%<br />

1995 Beer containers only Refillable<br />

beer 95.5%<br />

Dom beer<br />

74%<br />

Glass 34%<br />

Overall<br />

residential<br />

1992<br />

(revised<br />

1999)<br />

All except milk<br />

1997 Beverage containers<br />

smaller than 5l, excluding<br />

milk, dietary supplements<br />

and medicine.<br />

31%<br />

Refillable<br />

beer 96%<br />

Dom beer<br />

75%<br />

Nonalcoholic<br />

75%<br />

Refillable<br />

beer 95%<br />

Domestic<br />

beer 55%<br />

Deposit Deposit<br />

Redemption<br />

Redemption<br />

Site<br />

Site<br />

retail outlets<br />

(for beer bottles<br />

and cans only)<br />

Non-alcoholic $0.05<br />

1l<br />

Alcoholic (not incl.<br />

beer)<br />

$0.10 < 1l<br />

$0.20 >1l Beer $1.2<br />

per dozen<br />

$0.10 Retailer<br />

500ml $0.20<br />

Non-alcoholic $0.08<br />

($0.04 back)<br />

Alcoholic (excluding<br />

beer) $0.20<br />

($0.10 back)<br />

Beer varies -full refund<br />

Depots or<br />

retailers (all<br />

retailers obliged<br />

to take back as<br />

much as they<br />

sell). Beer back<br />

to retailer.<br />

89 depots<br />

around the<br />

province.<br />

‘Green Depots’<br />

run as<br />

businesses.<br />

Beer returned<br />

to certain retail<br />

outlets.<br />

Driver Driver<br />

Reference<br />

Reference<br />

it was turned<br />

over to private<br />

sector<br />

Industry<br />

Opportunity<br />

government<br />

driven,<br />

implementation<br />

producer driven<br />

Industry<br />

Government, but<br />

brewers for beer<br />

system.<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org


Country Country System System<br />

separately, run by brewers.<br />

Only have to refund when<br />

customer buying (1 for 1),<br />

otherwise negotiable.<br />

Year Year <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Intro Intro Containers Containers Covered Covered Capture<br />

Capture<br />

Rate*<br />

Rate*<br />

Canada- Deposit-return system, 2005 All beverage containers Very new<br />

Northwest with additional handling<br />

except milk.<br />

system, so<br />

Territory charges for different<br />

no certain<br />

products/ materials in<br />

figures yet.<br />

container.<br />

Approx.<br />

72%<br />

Canada-<br />

Nova Scotia<br />

Canada-<br />

Ontario<br />

Canada-<br />

Prince<br />

Edward<br />

Island<br />

Canada-<br />

Quebec<br />

304<br />

Half-back deposit system.<br />

Full refund on refillables,<br />

half on non-refillables.<br />

Deposit-return system on<br />

alcoholic drinks containers<br />

only.<br />

Use <strong>of</strong> ‘Industry Standard<br />

Bottle’.<br />

Non-refillable drinks<br />

containers for beer or s<strong>of</strong>t<br />

drinks banned since 1977.<br />

Wine may have half-back<br />

system in place.<br />

Return-to-retail deposit<br />

system, with industry<br />

required to fund kerbside<br />

collection for containers<br />

not part <strong>of</strong> the system.<br />

29/09/09<br />

1977 ban,<br />

1984<br />

deposit<br />

All beverage containers<br />

except milk.<br />

Refillable<br />

beer 96%<br />

Dom. beer<br />

70%<br />

Alcoholic drinks containers Refillable<br />

‘industry<br />

standard<br />

bottles’<br />

beer 97%<br />

S<strong>of</strong>t drinks and alcoholic<br />

drinks. Wine may be<br />

included.<br />

All beer and s<strong>of</strong>t drinks<br />

containers (not juice, water<br />

and iced tea)<br />

Refillable<br />

beer 96%<br />

Wine/ spirit<br />

59%<br />

S<strong>of</strong>t 98%<br />

Refillable<br />

beer 98%<br />

Dom. beer<br />

76%<br />

Deposit Deposit<br />

Redemption<br />

Redemption<br />

Site<br />

Site<br />

when same number <strong>of</strong><br />

beer bought as<br />

empties returned.<br />

Wine or spirit $0.25<br />

Other $0.10<br />

Plus additional $0.05-<br />

0.10 handling fee<br />

Non-alcoholic $0.10<br />

Alc. refillable<br />

1l $0.20<br />

Alc. non-refillable<br />

500ml $0.20<br />

Containers up to<br />

630ml, or metal<br />

containers up to 1l<br />

$0.10 Over those sizes<br />

$0.20<br />

Non-al<br />

1l $0.70 Alc. $1.20<br />

per dozen, or ).07 each<br />

S<strong>of</strong>t drinks and beer<br />

cans<br />

$0.05<br />

Beer bottles $0.10<br />

Beer bottles and s<strong>of</strong>t<br />

drinks >450ml $0.20<br />

18 government<br />

depots or 26<br />

community<br />

depots.<br />

83 provincewide<br />

depots.<br />

Beer store only Brewers<br />

Mainly retailers<br />

(inc.<br />

supermarkets<br />

and<br />

convenience<br />

stores), also 15<br />

depots<br />

Retailers<br />

(including<br />

depanneurs -<br />

small<br />

convenience<br />

stores not<br />

usually<br />

included in<br />

Canada).<br />

Driver Driver<br />

Reference<br />

Reference<br />

RRFB-Resource<br />

Recovery Fund<br />

Board<br />

Government and<br />

industry.<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org


Country Country System System<br />

Year Year <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Intro Intro Containers Containers Covered Covered Capture<br />

Capture<br />

Rate*<br />

Rate*<br />

Canada- Deposit-return system plus 1973- Litter All beverage containers Refillable<br />

Saskatche environmental handling Control apart from milk (under beer 92%<br />

wan charge (EHC) for non- Regulations voluntary system).<br />

Dom. beer<br />

refillable containers, for (unclear,<br />

cans 95%<br />

recycling, and beer bottle appears the<br />

Alu. cans<br />

deposit system for deposit<br />

95%<br />

refillables.<br />

system<br />

Glass 83%<br />

introduced<br />

Overall<br />

to this in<br />

1998)<br />

86%<br />

Canada-<br />

Yukon<br />

USA-<br />

California<br />

USA-<br />

Connecticut<br />

305<br />

No kerbside collection.<br />

Deposit-return system,<br />

with ‘recycling club’ for<br />

children <strong>of</strong>fering ‘prizes’ as<br />

well as refund if certain<br />

numbers reached.<br />

Refillables not charged<br />

recycling fund fee, all<br />

others are.<br />

California Beverage<br />

Container Recycling and<br />

Litter Reduction Act<br />

Deposit-return system on<br />

non-refillable containers<br />

Beverage Container<br />

Deposit and Redemption<br />

Law<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

1998 All beverage containers<br />

except milk.<br />

1987<br />

(Expanded<br />

2000 to<br />

include all<br />

noncarbonated<br />

and nonalcoholic<br />

drinks<br />

excluding<br />

milk.)<br />

Non-refillable drinks<br />

containers, inc. beer,<br />

spirits, carbonated, fruit<br />

drinks and some vegetable<br />

juices. Not milk.<br />

1980 Beer, malt, s<strong>of</strong>t drinks and<br />

mineral water.<br />

Refillable<br />

bottles<br />

103%<br />

Non-refill.<br />

bottles<br />

113% (?)<br />

Liquor<br />

containers<br />

1L 79%<br />

(includes<br />

refillables)<br />

Alu 73%<br />

Glass 58%<br />

PET 46%<br />

HDPE 51%<br />

Overall<br />

61%<br />

Not<br />

recorded.<br />

In 2004<br />

Deposit Deposit<br />

Redemption<br />

Redemption<br />

Site<br />

Site<br />

Deposits vary widely Beer bottles<br />

for diff. materials and can only receive<br />

sizes<br />

full refund if<br />

Non-ref. glass<br />

returned to 10<br />

$0.40-1.00<br />

specific sites,<br />

Metal cans<br />

but can be<br />

$0.10-0.20<br />

returned for<br />

less at retailers.<br />

Other returns at<br />

71 SARCON site<br />

D=deposit, R=refund<br />

Liquor ref. D=$0.10<br />

R=$0.10<br />

Liquor non<br />

500ml D=$0.35<br />

R=$0.25<br />

Under 24oz $0.05<br />

Over 24oz $0.10<br />

22 depots or<br />

four Liquor<br />

Commission<br />

outlets<br />

Redemption<br />

centres (not<br />

retailers)<br />

$0.05 Redemption<br />

centres, or<br />

retailers (but<br />

Driver Driver<br />

Reference<br />

Reference<br />

Government www.BottleBill.org<br />

http://www.sarcsarca<br />

n.ca/sarcan/faqs.php<br />

Government www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

http://www.cga.ct.gov<br />

/2005/rpt/2005-R-


Country Country System System<br />

Year Year <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Intro Intro Containers Containers Covered Covered Capture<br />

Capture Deposit Deposit<br />

Redemption<br />

Redemption Driver Driver<br />

Reference<br />

Reference<br />

Rate*<br />

Rate*<br />

Site<br />

Site<br />

Deposit-return system. CRI<br />

only for brands<br />

0836.htm<br />

estimated<br />

/products they<br />

recycling<br />

rate to be<br />

similar to<br />

Massachus<br />

etts <strong>of</strong> 69%<br />

sell).<br />

USA- Beverage Container 1982 All non-aluminium beer, Not $0.05 Retail stores,<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

Delaware Legislation<br />

Wholesale malt, carbonated, mineral recorded.<br />

but only for<br />

Deposit-return system 1983 Retail water and soda water<br />

brands they<br />

containers less than 2<br />

quarts (approx. 1.9L).<br />

sell.<br />

USA-Hawaii Deposit Beverage<br />

2002 All beverage containers 72% for $0.05 Redemption Government www.BottleBill.org<br />

Container Law Deposit-<br />

excluding milk and dairy 2008<br />

centres or<br />

return system<br />

derived products, except<br />

retailers (if not<br />

tea and c<strong>of</strong>fee or liquor<br />

within 2miles <strong>of</strong><br />

containers.<br />

red. centre in<br />

highly pop.<br />

areas, or if<br />

under 5,000sq<br />

ft <strong>of</strong> retail<br />

space<br />

USA-Iowa Beverage Container 1979 Beer, s<strong>of</strong>t drinks, soda 93% Not less than $0.05 Redemption<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

Deposit Law<br />

water, mineral water, wine,<br />

centres or<br />

Deposit-return system.<br />

liquor and wine coolers.<br />

retailers (who<br />

Deposit containers banned<br />

can refuse if<br />

from landfill in 1990.<br />

they have an<br />

agreement with<br />

former).<br />

USA- Maine Refillable Beverage 1978 Beer, s<strong>of</strong>t drink, wine Not Wine and liquor $0.15 Redemption<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

Maine Container Law Deposit-<br />

cooler, mineral water. recorded. Other $0.05<br />

centres or<br />

return system<br />

Expanded to include wine,<br />

retailers (who<br />

liquor, water and non-<br />

can refuse if<br />

alcoholic drinks in 1989.<br />

they have an<br />

agreement with<br />

former).<br />

USA- Beverage Container 1983 Beer, s<strong>of</strong>t drinks and 69% $0.05 Any retail<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

Massachus Recovery Law<br />

carbonated water.<br />

establishment<br />

etts Deposit-return system<br />

that sells the<br />

container.<br />

306<br />

29/09/09


Country Country System System<br />

Year Year <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Intro Intro Containers Containers Covered Covered Capture<br />

Capture Deposit Deposit<br />

Redemption<br />

Redemption Driver Driver<br />

Reference<br />

Reference<br />

Rate*<br />

Rate*<br />

Site<br />

Site<br />

USA- Michigan Beverage 1978 Beer, s<strong>of</strong>t drinks,<br />

97% $0.10 Retail stores wwiw.BottleBill.org<br />

Michigan Container Act<br />

carbonated and mineral<br />

Deposit-return system<br />

water. Wine coolers and<br />

canned cocktails in 1988.<br />

USA- New New York State Refillable 1983 Beer and other malt drinks, S<strong>of</strong>t drink Minimum <strong>of</strong> $0.05 Retail stores<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

York Container Law<br />

carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks, 62%<br />

and redemption<br />

Deposit-return system<br />

wine coolers, mineral and Beer 77%<br />

centres.<br />

soda waters.<br />

Wine<br />

coolers<br />

65%<br />

Overall<br />

70%<br />

USA- The Beverage Container 1972 Beer, malt, carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t Overall Standardized refill Retail stores. www.BottleBill.org<br />

Oregon Act<br />

drinks, mineral and soda 84% bottles $0.02<br />

Deposit-return system<br />

water and (as <strong>of</strong> 2009)<br />

Non-standardized and<br />

Only US deposit law with<br />

water and flavoured water.<br />

non-refillable $0.05<br />

no handling fee.<br />

Bottles and cans under 3L<br />

USA- Beverage Container Law 1973 Beer, s<strong>of</strong>t drinks, malt, Overall 90- Liquor above 50ml Retail stores<br />

www.BottleBill.org<br />

Vermont Deposit-return system<br />

soda and mineral water, 95% $0.15<br />

and redemption<br />

mixed wine and liquor<br />

(added 1987).<br />

Other $0.05<br />

centres.<br />

Source: Oakdene Hollins (2008) Refillable Glass Beverage Container Systems in the UK, Report for WRAP, 26 June 2008.<br />

The report notes that capture rate includes containers returned for recycling as well as refilling. Separate figures were not so readily available. Unless<br />

specifically listed as something else, the monetary unit is American dollars. The only exception is Canada where the Canadian dollar is used.<br />

Percentages given for US capture rates are taken from various sources, <strong>of</strong>ten telephone conversations by the Bottle Bill researchers. For more detailed<br />

references see www.BottleBill.org<br />

307<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


16.3.2 Sweden<br />

Deposit refund schemes are in place in Sweden for glass, PET and aluminium drinks<br />

containers. Both refillable and one-way containers are managed under the system. A<br />

number <strong>of</strong> materials-specialist companies manage the scheme, for example, Ab<br />

Svenska Returpack-Pet, Svenska Returglas 50-Cl Ab and Ab Svenska Returpack.<br />

Deposits are paid as follows: 327<br />

308<br />

� Cans: €0.04;<br />

� 0.33 L glass bottle: €0.05;<br />

� 0.50 L glass bottle: €0.08;<br />

� ≤ 1 L non-refillable PET bottle: €0.09; and<br />

� > 1 L non-refillable PET bottle: €0.18.<br />

In one small Swedish municipality, a deposit-refund system has been put into place<br />

for batteries. A very small (€0.03) deposit is levied on each battery sold, and this is<br />

redeemed when the battery is returned to one <strong>of</strong> the shops participating in the<br />

scheme. The estimated result is that approximately 80% <strong>of</strong> batteries are returned.<br />

The cost <strong>of</strong> the system is covered by the municipal budget.<br />

16.3.3 Germany<br />

For car batteries, the consumer has to pay €7.50 if he buys a new car battery without<br />

returning a used one. A number <strong>of</strong> states in the USA also operate these schemes.<br />

Usually the replaced battery must be returned to the retailer <strong>of</strong> the new one within 30<br />

days.<br />

For beverage containers, Germany has a deposit refund scheme on non-refillable<br />

containers as a result <strong>of</strong> the failure to meet certain recycling and reuse targets that<br />

were set in the Packaging Ordinance. Germany differs from the Scandinavian model<br />

because no single enterprise is given the sole right or obligation to operate a<br />

nationwide system. The DPG (Deutsche Pfandsystem GmbH) was established to<br />

coordinate the deposit refund system making it possible for the independent system<br />

participants to operate on an equal and fair basis (see Annex 17.0).<br />

16.3.4 Taiwan<br />

Taiwan has used a deposit refund system for PET bottles since 1989. Manufacturers<br />

and importers pay fees into a recycling management fund, and the end-consumers<br />

are given a refund when they return the bottle to a designated collection site. The<br />

fees are set by a Recycling Fund <strong>Management</strong> Board, on a level per kilogram plus the<br />

per bottle refund amount. For example, in 1998, PET bottles attracted a fee <strong>of</strong><br />

327 Sveriges Brygerier, accessed 2009, http://www.sverigesbryggerier.se/eng/1-emballage/1index.html<br />

29/09/09


NT$13.01 per kg (US$0.39 at January 1998 rates) for single material containers,<br />

plus a refund amount <strong>of</strong> NT$0.70 (US$0.02 at January 1998 rates) per bottle.<br />

Recycling rates started from a low base but were 41% in 1991. By 1992, the PET<br />

recycling rate had jumped to 80%. 328 The scheme then ran into problems with<br />

manufacturers’ not registering with the scheme, under-reporting production, and not<br />

paying fees so that the fund ran into a deficit and had to reduce the refund from<br />

around US$0.06 to around US$0.02. 329 However, recycling rates continue to be high,<br />

reaching 100% and remaining there (which does however, suggest that there<br />

continues to be some under-reporting <strong>of</strong> production). In 2007, over 97,000 tonnes<br />

were recycled.<br />

16.3.5 Other Countries<br />

Many other countries in Europe, as well as countries in Asia and the Americas use the<br />

deposit refund system for beverage containers.<br />

Eleven US states have a legal deposit on bottles and cans for beer and s<strong>of</strong>t drinks. Six<br />

states also have deposits on mineral water containers. Deposits are made mandatory<br />

through the State’s ‘bottle bills’ and range from 2.5¢ to 15¢ per container. According<br />

to the US Container Recycling Institute, beverage container recycling rates are far<br />

higher (72% on average by weight) in states with bottle bills than those without (28%<br />

recycling rate). 330 In most states, retailers are required to take back containers that<br />

are in their product line, even if the product was not purchased through their store. In<br />

some states (e.g. Maine and California) retailers are exempt where they are near to<br />

redemption (civic amenity) sites.<br />

Deposit refund arrangements for containers are also in place in most Canadian<br />

provinces and are also common in Europe. According to a UK report for Friends <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Earth, glass and PET bottle reuse rates as high as 90% are found in Denmark,<br />

Sweden, Germany and Finland. 331 Such schemes raise awareness and help to change<br />

consumer attitudes and behaviour. They have also been shown (in the USA) to have a<br />

low direct cost per tonne <strong>of</strong> material recovered although the administrative costs can<br />

be high if the scheme is not well designed and implemented. In the USA the states<br />

with bottle bills also have approximately three times the national average market<br />

share for refillable beverage containers, i.e. around 15% rather than around 5%. 332<br />

328 D. O’Connor (1996), Applying Economic Instruments In Developing Countries: From Theory To<br />

Implementation, Report for the OECD Development Centre, May 1996 web.idrc.ca/uploads/user-<br />

S/10536145810ACF2AE.pdf<br />

329 Asia-Pacific Environmental Innovation Strategies (2004) Deposit-Refund Systems for PET bottles in<br />

Taiwan, Report for Taiwan Environmental Protection Administration, December 2004,<br />

www.iges.or.jp/APEIS/RISPO/inventory/db/pdf/0133.pdf<br />

330 http://www.bottlebill.org<br />

331 Eunomia (2002), Maximising Recycling Rates, Tackling Residuals, Report for Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth,<br />

http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/maximising_recycling_rates_report.pdf<br />

332 Robert C. Anderson (2000) The United States Experience with Economic Incentives for Protecting<br />

the Environment, Report for US EPA, Nov 2004.<br />

309<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


All the provinces <strong>of</strong> Canada operate some deposit-refund systems for drinks<br />

containers. The beer industry organises collection and refilling <strong>of</strong> its refillable bottles<br />

and has a return rate <strong>of</strong> 90-99%. For other drinks containers, industry associations<br />

fund the kerbside recycling programs run by municipalities. They use a number <strong>of</strong><br />

different mechanisms to raise fees:<br />

310<br />

� Container recycling fee. This reflects the net cost <strong>of</strong> recycling, and therefore<br />

depends on the material and the recovery rate. These range from zero to<br />

$0.08;<br />

� Environmental handling charge. $0.03 to $0.07 per unit, depending on size<br />

and material. The provincial government collect the funds to operate the<br />

program and retain any surplus;<br />

� Beverage container levy. $0.02 per unit, used to finance 80% <strong>of</strong> kerbside<br />

collection;<br />

� Half-back. Represents half <strong>of</strong> the deposit paid on a non-refillable container.<br />

In systems other than the half-back (in which only half the deposit is refunded to the<br />

consumer on return), the whole deposit – between $0.05 and $0.40 – is refunded on<br />

return <strong>of</strong> the container.<br />

There is also some application <strong>of</strong> the concept in relation to other waste streams.<br />

Austria has deposit-refund schemes for light bulbs/tubes, batteries and refrigeration<br />

equipment. The US State <strong>of</strong> Rhode Island requires a US$5 deposit on all replacement<br />

vehicle tyres. The deposit is refunded if the customer returns the old tyres to the point<br />

<strong>of</strong> sale within 14 days <strong>of</strong> purchasing new tyres. It is also used for pesticide containers<br />

in some US states.<br />

The OECD noted in 2001 that among middle-income countries, South Korea has one<br />

<strong>of</strong> the most extensive deposit systems in terms <strong>of</strong> items covered. Under a 1991<br />

amendment to its Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act, South Korea introduced a<br />

comprehensive deposit program in 1992. The products affected by the system<br />

include packaging, batteries, tyres, oil, televisions, air conditioners and washing<br />

machines. Producers and importers <strong>of</strong> the listed products pay the deposits into a<br />

“Special Account for Environmental Improvement” and receive refunds as they collect<br />

and treat the resulting post-consumer waste. The products covered and the size <strong>of</strong><br />

the deposit were modified in 1993 and again in 1996. The largest deposit applied to<br />

large tyres and amounted to about $0.40. The deposit on paper, metal, glass and<br />

plastic packaging was a fraction <strong>of</strong> a US cent per container. 333<br />

New Zealand is currently examining the case for container deposit legislation. This is<br />

specifically regarded as a combination <strong>of</strong> product tax (the deposit) and recycling<br />

subsidy (the refund). The system being considered is likely to be based upon the<br />

South Australian model, in which the consumer takes the empty container to a small<br />

local collector and receives the refund, and the collectors give the product to 3 super-<br />

333 Robert C. Anderson (2004) The United States Experience with Economic Incentives for Protecting<br />

the Environment, Report for US EPA, Nov 2004.<br />

29/09/09


collectors. These super-collectors receive the deposit from the brand-owner and pass<br />

on the material to the recycler. The New Zealand system will attempt to address the<br />

perceived weaknesses <strong>of</strong> this system, which are:<br />

311<br />

� High collection costs;<br />

� Lack <strong>of</strong> incentive for brand-owners to assist in recycling, as they keep<br />

unclaimed deposits;<br />

� Sorting by brand required <strong>of</strong> the materials collected; and<br />

� Excessive market power held by the super-collectors.<br />

To do this, it is proposed that collection will be at point <strong>of</strong> sale, unclaimed deposits<br />

will go to a public body, and no sorting between brands will be required. 334<br />

16.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

To implement and manage deposit refund systems, there is normally a fund<br />

holder/manager which is an organisation that carries out the following functions:<br />

� Accepts the fees from the manufacturers/importers and the consumers;<br />

� Organises the collection systems; and<br />

� Manages the refund payments to the bottle collectors<br />

In Denmark, it is Dansk Retursystem A/S that is responsible for the implementation<br />

and administration <strong>of</strong> the system, in Sweden there are several in this position, each<br />

dealing with a specific material, such as Ab Svenska Returpack-Pet, Svenska<br />

Returglas 50-Cl Ab and Ab Svenska Returpack.<br />

The recycling fees or deposits are usually set by a body specified for the purpose such<br />

as the Resources Recycling Fee Rate <strong>Review</strong> Committee (in Taiwan). Fee setting can<br />

be a political decision.<br />

Another key player in the implementation is usually the Environmental Protection<br />

Agency <strong>of</strong> the country, which monitors enforcement and performance.<br />

The retailers are also involved in implementation, as they have to either be equipped<br />

with reverse vending machines or have sufficient space to keep returned containers<br />

until collection so as to allow for return <strong>of</strong> the containers.<br />

16.5 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The following selected references from this review give some specific information on<br />

the performance <strong>of</strong> deposit refund systems:<br />

� Enviros (2004) <strong>International</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Reduction Practice: Final<br />

Report For Defra, October 2004;<br />

334 Covec Report (2008) Potential Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation (Solids) Bill: Update Report,<br />

Report for Packaging Council <strong>of</strong> New Zealand, May 2008, http://www.pca.org.au/uploads/00548.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


312<br />

� Robert C. Anderson (2004) <strong>International</strong> Experience with Economic Incentives<br />

for Protecting the Environment, Report for US EPA, Nov 2004;<br />

� Robert C. Anderson (2001) The United States Experience with Economic<br />

Incentives for Protecting the Environment, Report for US EPA, Jan 2001;<br />

� Covec Report (2008) Potential Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation (Solids) Bill:<br />

Update Report, Report for Packaging Council <strong>of</strong> New Zealand, May 2008,<br />

http://www.pca.org.au/uploads/00548.pdf ;<br />

� N. Tojo, T. Lindhqvist and G. Davis (2001) OECD Seminar on Extended<br />

Producer Responsibility, EPR: Programme Implementation and Assessment,<br />

Seminar for the OECD, December 2001<br />

� RDC-Environment & Pira <strong>International</strong> (2003) Evaluation <strong>of</strong> costs and benefits<br />

for the achievement <strong>of</strong> reuse and recycling targets for the different packaging<br />

materials in the frame <strong>of</strong> the packaging and packaging waste directive, Report<br />

for the European Commission, March 2003<br />

� D. O’Connor (1996) Applying Economic Instruments in Developing Countries:<br />

From Theory to Implementation, OECD Development Centre, May 1996<br />

� ERM (2008), <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Packaging Deposit Systems for the UK, Report for<br />

DEFRA, December 2008, accessed from<br />

http://randd.defra.gov.uk/Document.aspx?Document=WR1203_7722_FRP.p<br />

df<br />

16.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

Deposit-refund systems are reported, in the literature, to have a range <strong>of</strong> possible<br />

environmental benefits. The key ones mentioned in the literature are:<br />

� Increasing the use <strong>of</strong> / reducing the extent <strong>of</strong> decline in the use <strong>of</strong> refillables;<br />

� Increasing the recycling <strong>of</strong> containers covered by deposits (for refill or<br />

recycling);<br />

� Reducing the extent <strong>of</strong> littering; and<br />

� Avoiding harmful chemicals being mobilised in the environment (usually not in<br />

beverage schemes, e.g. lead acid batteries, or pesticides).<br />

In addition, the logistics may or may not be more efficient. These issues are examined<br />

in turn below.<br />

16.6.1 Maintaining Use <strong>of</strong> Refillables<br />

Not all deposit schemes are designed with the intention <strong>of</strong> shoring up the market<br />

share <strong>of</strong> refillables, and where they are, they are not always well designed. The<br />

question we are interested in this Section is whether this is an environmentally<br />

justifiable goal.<br />

29/09/09


A study in 2002 reviewed the outcomes <strong>of</strong> 11 different LCAs comparing refillable<br />

against one-way packaging (including glass). 335 The study suggested that in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

five types <strong>of</strong> air pollutants, the use <strong>of</strong> refillable containers was, on balance, beneficial.<br />

Refillables were also found to generate less solid waste per unit volume <strong>of</strong> packaged<br />

beverage. Comparing refillables with one-way bottles, furthermore, revealed that<br />

refillables use less water and use less energy. However, cans compared favourably to<br />

refillable glass bottles in respect <strong>of</strong> water pollution and energy use. Conversely, a<br />

study summarising the results <strong>of</strong> seven LCA studies <strong>of</strong> refillable glass versus<br />

aluminium showed that all LCAs favoured refillable packaging with a 47-82%<br />

reduction in water use.<br />

IFEU undertook an LCA on beer packaging in Germany and concluded that from the<br />

perspective <strong>of</strong> climate change, re-usable PET and glass bottles had the least<br />

environmental burden producing less than half the emissions (expressed in CO2<br />

equivalent) <strong>of</strong> the three one-way systems (see Figure 16-1).<br />

Figure 16-1: Greenhouse Gas Impacts <strong>of</strong> Different Packaging Options<br />

Source: IFEU (2003) Relevant Packaging for Beer, LCA III, in Peter Lee, Paul Vaughan,<br />

Caroline Bartlett, Tracy Bhamra, Vicky L<strong>of</strong>thouse and Rhoda Trimingham (2008)<br />

Refillable Glass Beverage Container Systems in the UK, report for WRAP, June 2008.<br />

Interestingly, the same organization – IFEU – undertook a separate analysis on<br />

refillable packaging on behalf <strong>of</strong> PETCORE (the PET recycling company). 336 This study<br />

suggested a more equivocal view. It highlighted the significance <strong>of</strong> assumptions<br />

regarding collection and recovery <strong>of</strong> used packaging, and distribution logistics.<br />

The 2006 Beer Store Annual Report 2006 included LCAs provided by the Canadian<br />

Government. The Beer Store, which is responsible for 75% <strong>of</strong> all beer sold in Ontario,<br />

335 Institute for Local Self-reliance (2002) Environmental Benefits <strong>of</strong> Refillable Beverage Containers,<br />

Washington: ILSR.<br />

336 IFEU (2004) Okobilanz fur PET-Einwegsysteme unter Berucksichtigung der Sekundarprodukte,<br />

Repoirt for PETCORE, August 2004.<br />

313<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


eported that on average, each glass bottle is washed and refilled 12-15 times before<br />

being recycled. It calculates that re-using refillable glass bottles an average 15 times<br />

results in an overall energy saving <strong>of</strong> 2.4 million gJ and the avoidance <strong>of</strong> nearly<br />

160,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gases. 337<br />

A study undertaken for the EC in 2005 included a review <strong>of</strong> LCA studies that<br />

compared refillables against one-way systems. The report found that no type <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging was clearly always better or always worse for the environment, irrespective<br />

<strong>of</strong> the assumptions used. The report concluded that the findings <strong>of</strong> these studies<br />

were highly dependent on the product supply system, return rates, transport<br />

distances, control mechanisms, incentives such as deposits and electricity generation<br />

methods. 338 The relationship between capture rate and transport distance was<br />

reviewed in detail and Table 16-2 shows the findings from the analysis. The analysis<br />

suggested refillables (glass) would be beneficial when the transport distance is below<br />

100km and the capture rate is high, and one-way containers would be beneficial<br />

when transport distance is high and capture rates are low. It suggested that refillable<br />

PET bottles may be the best option for short distribution distances (


315<br />

The existing studies show that the environmental comparison <strong>of</strong> refillables<br />

versus one-way containers is not a simple one and that a number <strong>of</strong> factors<br />

need to be considered. Three key factors, cited in a number <strong>of</strong> the studies, are<br />

transport transport distance, capture rate for for reuse and collection collection rate for for for recycling.<br />

recycling.<br />

Another factor they do not mention is the number <strong>of</strong> uses per container, which is<br />

partly a function <strong>of</strong> capture rate, but also a function <strong>of</strong> the number <strong>of</strong> uses prior to<br />

breakage. This is usually a key factor in such studies (i.e. how many ‘lives’ does a<br />

container have before it enters the ‘discard’ phase).<br />

The suggestion is that the studies are not conclusive. They also suggest, however,<br />

that some variables – such as transport – should be entitled to vary freely. Issues<br />

such as transport distance are, however, amenable to being influenced by policy.<br />

LCAs appear to treat this as an exogenous variable, yet clearly, it is not, and one<br />

might legitimately ask whether restriction <strong>of</strong> transport movements might not be a<br />

legitimate area for policy intervention.<br />

This important point was raised in the study by Ecolas-PIRA, where it was suggested<br />

that: ‘This inevitably leads to debates on the proper balance’ between Internal Market<br />

and environmental objectives, to which there is no simple answer.’ 341<br />

The actual outcomes <strong>of</strong> some deposit schemes are not always as intended. To the<br />

extent that the German scheme was designed to increase the market share <strong>of</strong><br />

refillables, it seems to have failed, partly as a consequence <strong>of</strong> high deposit rates (see<br />

Section 17.0). Bevington notes: 342<br />

The mandatory 25 cent deposit on non-refillables is much higher than the<br />

commercially-determined deposits on refillables: 8 cents (glass) and 15 cents<br />

(PET). This was intended to encourage consumers to buy refillables, in order to<br />

protect the refill market. A perverse result <strong>of</strong> this has been that consumers<br />

who do not intend to return their empties buy refillables so they lose a smaller<br />

deposit. Thus the return rate for refillables has fallen.<br />

The deposit has failed to protect refillables, and their market share has fallen<br />

in all categories except beer since 2003, as shown in the chart below. They<br />

are below the levels in 2001, just before the deposit took effect. Most <strong>of</strong> the<br />

non-refillables are PET, as consumption <strong>of</strong> cans has not recovered. The fact<br />

that beer is not commonly sold in PET, together with the conservative nature<br />

<strong>of</strong> the German beer market, explains why refill levels for beer have been<br />

maintained. Government data for 2006 are not yet available, but industry data<br />

suggests that refill levels declined further in 2006 for all drinks categories<br />

including beer.<br />

341 Ecolas – Pira (2005) Study on the Implementation <strong>of</strong> Directive 94/62/EC on Packaging and<br />

Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> and Options to Strengthen Prevention and Re-use <strong>of</strong> Packaging, Final Report to the<br />

European Commission, Report 03/07884.<br />

342 G. Bevington (2008) A Deposit and Refund Scheme in Ireland, Report commissioned by Repak Ltd.,<br />

September 2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


This may reflect the ease with which consumers can make use <strong>of</strong> the DSD system as<br />

an alternative route – free, to themselves, at the point <strong>of</strong> disposal – for ensuring an<br />

environmentally sound management <strong>of</strong> beverage containers, namely, recycling.<br />

The above example does not necessarily imply that a scheme could not be designed<br />

where refillables were not encouraged. For example, if households were incentivised<br />

to reduce the use <strong>of</strong> recycling services through applying small charges on recycling<br />

services, this might do more to improve the incentive to use refillables rather than<br />

one-trip packaging. More likely, the combined effect <strong>of</strong> a primary material tax and a<br />

deposit – as happens in Denmark – might reinforce the case for refillables. Finally, if<br />

deposit schemes are successful in achieving high captures <strong>of</strong> material, it seems<br />

reasonable to ask why it should be necessary to retain a second collection route for<br />

the materials targeted by the deposit refund scheme. This important point is taken up<br />

below in respect <strong>of</strong> costs.<br />

Deposit-refund schemes have been used to encourage the refillable container<br />

market, particularly for beer bottles, in Canada and some states <strong>of</strong> the USA. As<br />

suggested above, where distances to transport the bottles are relatively short this<br />

probably has a positive environmental benefit. Refillable PET bottles are increasingly<br />

an alternative to the heavier, traditional refillable glass, particularly for the large<br />

volume containers.<br />

16.6.2 Increasing Recycling<br />

To the extent that re-use might not be the objective <strong>of</strong> a deposit-refund scheme, it<br />

becomes <strong>of</strong> interest to know whether deposit refund schemes can increase recycling.<br />

This is not the same question as that <strong>of</strong> whether deposit refund schemes achieve<br />

higher return rates than any alternative policies. This question is discussed, and it is<br />

touched upon below, since this is <strong>of</strong>ten the question addressed by those discussing<br />

deposit refunds. It would not, in and <strong>of</strong> itself, be evidence <strong>of</strong> the superiority <strong>of</strong> one<br />

instrument relative to another. If the improvement in performance was obtained at a<br />

cost that does not justify the benefit, then one might reasonably argue that an<br />

instrument with enhanced performance is one where benefits are not justified by<br />

costs.<br />

16.6.2.1 Effects <strong>of</strong> Deposit Schemes on Recycling Rates<br />

Ideally, one has some indication <strong>of</strong> ‘before’ and ‘after’ performance, controlling for<br />

other variables. To some extent, this is made difficult by the absence <strong>of</strong> data <strong>of</strong> a<br />

usable form. Surprisingly few studies actually take this approach.<br />

Some data allows for comparison <strong>of</strong> performance in areas with and without deposits,<br />

In the US, in 1999, the recycling performance <strong>of</strong> states with and without deposits in<br />

place is shown in Figure 16-2. The recycling rates, and the number <strong>of</strong> containers<br />

recovered per capita, were far higher in the deposit states.<br />

316<br />

29/09/09


Figure 16-2: Performance <strong>of</strong> US States with and Without Deposits, 1999<br />

317<br />

Recycling rate (%) and per capita containers<br />

recovered in the US (1999)<br />

490<br />

72 28<br />

Also <strong>of</strong> interest is the performance <strong>of</strong> deposit schemes in the context <strong>of</strong> wider<br />

recycling systems. In Sweden, for example, the recycling rate for plastic packaging<br />

increased from 17% to 30% between 2003 and 2005 (44% in 2006). In the same<br />

period, recycling rates for PET under the deposit scheme were 77% to 82% (85% in<br />

2007). This, in and <strong>of</strong> itself, might not prove much. The components <strong>of</strong> plastic<br />

packaging are many and varied, and PET bottles are readily recyclable. Perhaps more<br />

telling, however, is the performance in respect <strong>of</strong> metals. Metal packaging recycling<br />

rates were around 65% in 2004-2005, but the recycling rate for aluminium under the<br />

deposit system was 85% to 86% in the years 2002 to 2007. More impressive still is<br />

the return rate for glass bottles which is 99% on 33cl bottles and 90% on 50cl<br />

bottles. 343 In Denmark, return rates in 2007 were 84% for cans, 93% for plastic<br />

bottles and 91% for glass bottles. 344<br />

Similarly, in Germany, recycling rates in 2005 for plastics, tinplate and aluminium<br />

were 50%, 85%, 76% and 79% for plastics, tinplate, aluminium and glass,<br />

respectively. The reported return rates under the deposit scheme are 95-98%, but<br />

these rates are not <strong>of</strong>ficial. 345<br />

Figure 16-3 shows collection rates achieved in 2002 in deposit schemes. This shows<br />

that very few countries see low rates <strong>of</strong> return, with some jurisdictions achieving close<br />

to 100% return rates. As would be expected under economic theory, deposit<br />

343 http://www.sverigesbryggerier.se/eng/1-emballage/1-index.html, accessed January 2009.<br />

344 ERM (2008) <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Packaging Deposit Systems for the UK, Report for DEFRA, December 2008,<br />

accessed from http://randd.defra.gov.uk/Document.aspx?Document=WR1203_7722_FRP.pdf<br />

345 Wolfgang Ringel (2008) The German Deposit System on One Way Beverage Packaging,<br />

Presentation to the first Global Deposit Summit, Berlin 2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

191<br />

Deposit states (10) Non-deposit states (40)<br />

Recycling rate Containers per capita recovered


schemes’ return rates increase as the deposit increases, these leading to an<br />

enhanced incentive (see Figure 16-4). Figures for Denmark are shown in Figure 16-5.<br />

Figure 16-3: Collection Rates for Non-refillable Containers in Deposit Systems, 2002<br />

100<br />

75<br />

50<br />

25<br />

Note: Figures based on data collected from system operators, data from 2002<br />

Source: Wolfgang Ringel (2008) Introduction on Deposit, Scottish Government Litter<br />

Summit, Edinburgh 26 th November 2008.<br />

Figure 16-4: Relation Between Level <strong>of</strong> Deposit and Return Rate<br />

Collection rate (% )<br />

Source: System operators, Container Recycling Institute, Data from 1997-2002<br />

Taiwan differs from the European context, as the deposit refund scheme started<br />

without any other producer responsibility systems in place. The scheme therefore<br />

acted in isolation to increase recycling, first <strong>of</strong> PET and later with a number <strong>of</strong> other<br />

materials. As described earlier, Taiwan now claims a 100% PET recycling rate, using<br />

its deposit-refund system.<br />

318<br />

0<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

29/09/09<br />

59 59<br />

Collection rate in deposit systems for non-refillable containers (%)<br />

65<br />

69 70 70 70<br />

75 77 77 77<br />

80<br />

83 83 83 84 84 84<br />

90<br />

93 93 95 95 96<br />

California<br />

Prince Edward<br />

New Foundland<br />

Massachusetts<br />

Connecticut<br />

Maine<br />

New York<br />

South Australia<br />

New Brunswick<br />

Ontario<br />

Quebec<br />

Alberta<br />

Denmark<br />

Nova Scotia<br />

Saskatchewan<br />

British Columbia<br />

Oregon<br />

Sweden<br />

Vermont<br />

Iowa<br />

Norway<br />

Finland<br />

Manitoba<br />

Michigan<br />

0,0 2,0 4,0 6,0 8,0 10,0 12,0 14,0 16,0<br />

Deposit (€ cents per container)


Figure 16-5: Return Percentages <strong>of</strong> One Way & Refillable Beverages<br />

Source: Christian Fischer (2008) Producer Responsibility Schemes Versus Deposits<br />

and Taxes- Danish Experiences, PRO Europe Congress, 15 May 2008<br />

It is common to hear it suggested that it is not the case that recycling rates are higher<br />

under deposit schemes. However, those who suggest this usually do so on the basis<br />

<strong>of</strong> reviewing recycling rates for all packaging. For example, EUROPEN, argues: 346<br />

319<br />

There are no compensating benefits with regard to an overall improvement in<br />

recycling performance. The Perchards report showed that overall recycling<br />

rates in Member States with deposit systems are not higher than those <strong>of</strong><br />

comparable EU countries where there are no special arrangements for<br />

beverage containers.<br />

The problem with this appears to be that the Perchards report looked at rates for all<br />

packaging in seeking to make this point. Deposits do not apply to all packaging (a<br />

point that is frequently made to downplay the potential impact <strong>of</strong> deposits on total<br />

recycling rates, <strong>of</strong>ten by the same organisations who seek to downplay the potential<br />

effectiveness <strong>of</strong> deposit refunds by using statistics which cover all packaging).<br />

Perchards themselves state: 347<br />

It is certainly true that deposit systems for non-refillable beverage containers<br />

can achieve higher recycling rates for the beverage containers affected than<br />

when these containers are handled through general recycling systems.<br />

However European experience shows that deposit systems do do not not achieve achieve achieve a<br />

a<br />

346 EUROPEN (2007) Economic Instruments in Packaging and Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Brussels:<br />

EUROPEN.<br />

347 G. Bevington (2008) A Deposit and Refund Scheme in Ireland, Report commissioned by Repak Ltd.,<br />

September 2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


320<br />

29/09/09<br />

higher higher higher recycling recycling recycling rate rate rate for for for all all all packaging packaging packaging <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> a a a given given given material, material, because because because beverage<br />

beverage<br />

containers containers represent represent too too small small small a a proportio proportion proportio n <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the total total tonnage tonnage <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> that<br />

that<br />

packaging packaging packaging material.<br />

material.<br />

Drinks containers typically represent only about 10% <strong>of</strong> all packaging and the<br />

recycling rate for beverage containers in general recycling systems is likely to<br />

be higher than the recycling rate for all packaging <strong>of</strong> the same materials.<br />

They then allude to the performance <strong>of</strong> Belgium in respect <strong>of</strong> the recycling <strong>of</strong> all<br />

packaging even though this is clearly not a good comparator for reasons which the<br />

previous extract makes clear (the targeted materials – beverage containers – are a<br />

relatively small fraction <strong>of</strong> packaging). 348 In particular, the largest fraction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

packaging stream is always paper and card, which is also an easy, and relatively low<br />

cost, material to recycle. Consequently, in most countries, the packaging recycling<br />

rate will be heavily influenced by capture <strong>of</strong> a material that is irrelevant to any<br />

sensible discussion regarding deposit refund schemes.<br />

348 Perchards responded to a similar criticism in a previous report, where they had earlier suggested<br />

that the recycling rates achieved in deposit schemes were no greater than those achieved in other<br />

countries through presenting targets related to all packaging. They responded:<br />

We decided to make a comparison based on overall recycling rates achieved because the<br />

Packaging and Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directive repealed the Directive on containers <strong>of</strong> liquids for<br />

human consumption, reflecting that the scope <strong>of</strong> policy has broadened out to all packaging. A<br />

further expansion and/or restructuring <strong>of</strong> EU policy is now under consideration which may<br />

result in targets for all products <strong>of</strong> specific materials. Thus, specific arrangements just for<br />

beverage containers go against the trend in EU policy in this area.<br />

GRA has challenged our line <strong>of</strong> argument, saying that the fact that deposit systems handle<br />

only a small <strong>of</strong> packaging is no reason not to have a deposit system. GRA used a medical<br />

analogy to illustrate argument – if you have a medicine that can cure 10% <strong>of</strong> the patients, but<br />

not the other 90%, is there a reason not to use the medicine for the 10%? However, this is not<br />

an exact analogy, because a medicine does exist for a significant proportion <strong>of</strong> the other 90%<br />

<strong>of</strong> packaging, namely selective collection.<br />

Several other stakeholders have also challenged the basis <strong>of</strong> our comparison, arguing that a<br />

clearer picture would emerge from a comparison based on recycling rates for household<br />

packaging waste alone, or, even better, <strong>of</strong> beverage containers between deposit states and<br />

Member States relying on packaging recovery systems. Unfortunately, though, we were not<br />

able to obtain data which would have enabled us to pursue this suggestion.<br />

(Perchards (2005) Study on the Progress <strong>of</strong> the Implementation and Impact <strong>of</strong> Directive 94/62/EC on<br />

the Functioning <strong>of</strong> the Internal Market, Final Report to the European Commission, May 2005). This<br />

argument fails to counter the possibility that it might be possible to design a system which targets the<br />

10% through one system and targets the remaining 90% through another. No one advocating deposit<br />

refund scheme is necessarily arguing against ‘selective collection’ <strong>of</strong>, for example, cardboard, or wood.<br />

Equally, several successful selective collection systems for packaging – notably the Belgian one<br />

achieve high rates <strong>of</strong> recycling without targeting non-bottle plastics from households. So, the question<br />

remains open as to whether a complementary (as opposed to a parallel) system <strong>of</strong> selective collection<br />

and deposit refund system might be superior to either one acting independently, let alone the two<br />

operating in parallel with duplication in scope. This question has only really been examined in any<br />

study as far as we are aware (see later in this Section). Generally, the question regarding costs has not<br />

been properly answered for the simple reason that the question which really matters has not been<br />

interrogated in sufficient depth. The key variables are likely to be quite system dependent (which<br />

selective system is being ‘replaced’ by the type <strong>of</strong> complementary system being proposed here) and<br />

dependent upon the (assumed) costs <strong>of</strong> implementing a deposit scheme.


This is not to deny the possibility <strong>of</strong> high recycling rates <strong>of</strong> packaging being achieved<br />

without deposit refund schemes. Other EU countries have achieved impressive<br />

recycling performance without deposit-refund systems, such as Belgium.<br />

Notwithstanding very high overall rates <strong>of</strong> recycling for packaging, however, based on<br />

its Fost Plus managed packaging collection system, Belgium managed to recycle 67%<br />

<strong>of</strong> plastic bottles in 2007 (comprising both PET and HDPE) and 97.5% <strong>of</strong> metal<br />

packaging (steel and aluminium cans). 349 One might still argue, even in this case, that<br />

there might be room for improvement, through use <strong>of</strong> a deposit scheme, where<br />

plastic bottles are concerned.<br />

In the UK, Alupro, the aluminium industry’s trade body, says 98% <strong>of</strong> English<br />

households have kerbside collections <strong>of</strong> aluminium cans, but capture rates can be<br />

anywhere between 30% and 70%. 350 The ‘cans-only’ recycling rate is estimated to be<br />

52% in 2008. 351 Therefore, even with a ‘free to the consumer’ system (in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

marginal cost), and a very widespread coverage, the capture rate is still much less<br />

than is seen in the deposit-refund scheme countries. This may be partly a reflection <strong>of</strong><br />

the fact that 35% <strong>of</strong> aluminium cans are consumed away from home, in the<br />

workplace, and at sports, leisure and travel locations, according to Alupro. However,<br />

such a waste stream is one for which deposit refund schemes may be well suited to<br />

dealing with, not least since such containers are less likely to arise as litter where<br />

deposits are in place.<br />

16.6.3 Effects on Littering<br />

There is evidence to suggest that deposit refund policies can reduce litter and even<br />

reduce the number <strong>of</strong> lacerations caused by glass in the environment. 352 Several oneway<br />

deposit systems were implemented with the clear objective <strong>of</strong> reducing littering<br />

(e.g. Sweden, British Columbia, California, Michigan and others). Hawaii is a more<br />

recent example <strong>of</strong> this trend. The potential for deposit systems to be effective in<br />

reducing littering has an intuitively plausible rationale - if the deposit is significant,<br />

then if the consumer does decide to litter, the possibility exists that someone else will<br />

pick up the container to redeem the deposit.<br />

The Container Recycling Institute suggested significant reductions in littering following<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> deposits in some US states (see Figure 16-6). The effects on used<br />

beverage containers (UBCs) and on total litter are shown as being between 70-80%<br />

and 30-40%, respectively. It must be said, however, that all studies <strong>of</strong> this nature<br />

suffer in terms <strong>of</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong> clarity about the metric used to measure the contribution<br />

349 Fost Plus (2007) Annual Report, http://www.fostplus.be/files/EN/8/GB_AR.pdf<br />

350 Ends Report (2009) Defra Report Rejects the case for Bottle Deposits, January 2009<br />

http://www.endsreport.com/index.cfm?action=report.article&articleID=20119&q=deposit%20refund&<br />

boolean_mode=all<br />

351 Alupro website, http://www.alupro.org.uk/facts%20and%20figures.htm, accessed May 2009.<br />

352 M. Douglas Baker, MD, Sally E. Moore, and Paul H. Wise, MD, PhD, MPH, "The Impact <strong>of</strong> 'Bottle Bill'<br />

Legislation on the Incidence <strong>of</strong> Lacerations in Childhood", American Journal <strong>of</strong> Public Health, October<br />

1986.<br />

321<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


<strong>of</strong> beverage containers to total litter. It is not clear what the most relevant indicator<br />

should be (counts, volume, hazardousness, etc.) partly because no systematic studies<br />

have been carried out, to our knowledge, to understand the contribution <strong>of</strong> different<br />

attributes <strong>of</strong> litter to the disamenity experienced by those who experience litter. There<br />

is also the matter <strong>of</strong> cost to be considered since clean up <strong>of</strong> litter costs money. The<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> litter reduction on costs is considered below.<br />

Figure 16-6: Reduction in Littering in US States Linked to Deposit Schemes<br />

Where supposed counter-arguments to the ‘litter reduction’ effect are put forward,<br />

these very rarely challenge the likely reality <strong>of</strong> this effect. Indeed, the counterarguments<br />

tend to adopt the view that this effect is not significant because beverage<br />

containers constitute only a small proportion <strong>of</strong> litter. Even if one accepts the<br />

argument that this might be true, implicit in the counter-argument appears to be an<br />

assumption that if litter ‘is there’, then the amount <strong>of</strong> it is not a matter <strong>of</strong> any<br />

importance, or more specifically, that the reduction in the quantity <strong>of</strong> beverage<br />

packaging in litter is <strong>of</strong> no significance. Yet none <strong>of</strong> the literature actually <strong>of</strong>fers any<br />

evidence to support this implied claim. The validity <strong>of</strong> the implied claim is also<br />

affected by the nature <strong>of</strong> the assumption (as highlighted above) concerning the metric<br />

used to measure ‘litter’. What the right metric might be has not, as discussed above,<br />

been given adequate consideration by either advocates, or detractors, <strong>of</strong> the effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> deposit schemes.<br />

In Ireland, Perchards argue that: 353<br />

322<br />

The National Litter Survey for 2006 indicates that drinks containers (excluding<br />

cartons) represent 5.36% <strong>of</strong> total litter, with all packaging representing 13% <strong>of</strong><br />

litter. This indicates that a a deposit deposit could could reduce reduce the the incidence incidence <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> drinks drinks containers<br />

containers<br />

353 G. Bevington (2008) A Deposit and Refund Scheme in Ireland, Report commissioned by Repak Ltd.,<br />

September 2008.<br />

29/09/09<br />

Reduction <strong>of</strong> littering in 6 US states after the introduction <strong>of</strong> container<br />

deposit systems.<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

70%~80% reduction<br />

UBC litter reduced Total litter reduced<br />

NY OR VT ME MI IA<br />

Source: Container Recycling Institute, USA<br />

30%~40% reduction<br />

• Deposit on one-way<br />

containers reduces<br />

UBC littering by 70-<br />

80%<br />

• Deposit on one-way<br />

containers also<br />

reduces the total<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> littering by<br />

30-40%


323<br />

in in in packaging, packaging, packaging, but but but it it it would would would have have have little little impact impact impact on on on total total total litter litter. litter litter Other litter surveys<br />

undertaken around the world have reached the same conclusion. Through Repak,<br />

Irish industry is already helping to combat litter, and it is unlikely that a deposit<br />

would result in significant cost savings for Irish local authorities on litter<br />

abatement activities.<br />

A problem with this analysis is that it assumes that the relevant indicator regarding<br />

litter is the measure used in the Litter Survey. This actually measures ‘counts’ <strong>of</strong> litter.<br />

It could be argued that the disamenity effect <strong>of</strong> litter is a function more <strong>of</strong> its volume,<br />

and possibly, its potential to persist, than the number <strong>of</strong> items (i.e. the counts). In this<br />

respect, it is worth reporting that the 2007 National Litter Survey reports that the two<br />

most prominent items in litter in terms <strong>of</strong> counts are cigarette related litter,<br />

accounting for 46.7% <strong>of</strong> counts, and food related litter, accounting for 28% <strong>of</strong> counts.<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> the two combined– though certainly requiring clean-up – are less<br />

visible cigarette ends and chewing gum. Chewing gum clearly has the potential to<br />

cause nuisance in its own particular way. After these categories, the component with<br />

the highest number <strong>of</strong> counts is packaging items, at 11.75%, <strong>of</strong> which around 5.64% -<br />

roughly half – were beverage containers. 354<br />

Given the relative insignificance – in volume terms – <strong>of</strong> chewing gum and cigarette<br />

ends, it might reasonably be considered that beverage containers could actually<br />

constitute a significant proportion <strong>of</strong> litter when considered in volume terms. As a<br />

result, one might argue that they are not as insignificant – in terms <strong>of</strong> their<br />

contribution to the disamenity associated with litter – as the count number would<br />

suggest if, as seems not entirely implausible, some <strong>of</strong> the litter-related disamenity<br />

experienced by communities relates to litter’s visibility.<br />

Furthermore, in terms <strong>of</strong> value <strong>of</strong> materials in the litter stream, their contribution may<br />

also be significant. It is notable that the contribution <strong>of</strong> beverage containers to the<br />

litter count associated with packaging is around 50%, even though in weight terms,<br />

such containers account for only 10% or so <strong>of</strong> packaging in the waste stream. In other<br />

words, where packaging is concerned, beverage containers appear to figure in a<br />

disproportionately significant manner within litter. Hence, whilst many argue that<br />

deposits only address a fraction <strong>of</strong> all packaging, their effect on litter may address a<br />

form <strong>of</strong> packaging which contributes disproportionately to the problem <strong>of</strong> litter.<br />

In jurisdictions such as Hawaii, where the prevalence <strong>of</strong> beverage containers in litter<br />

has been a motivation for the scheme, the problem also extends to pollution <strong>of</strong> the<br />

sea. One report from the State <strong>of</strong> Hawaii shows how beverage containers have<br />

changed in terms <strong>of</strong> their prevalence in litter (debris) over time. 355 The data are<br />

shown in Table 16-3 and Table 16-4.<br />

354 TOBIN (2008) Litter Monitoring Body: System Results 2007, The National Litter Pollution Monitoring<br />

System Survey, Report for DoEHLG, June 2008,<br />

http://www.environ.ie/en/Environment/<strong>Waste</strong>/LitterPollution/NationalLitterMonitoringSystem/Publica<br />

tionsDocuments/FileDownLoad,18616,en.pdf<br />

355 State Of Hawaii <strong>Department</strong> Of Health (2008) Pursuant To Sections 342g-102.5(H), 342g-114.5(B),<br />

And 342g-123, Hawaii Revised Statutes, Requiring The <strong>Department</strong> Of Health To Give A Report On The<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 16-3: Number <strong>of</strong> Debris Found During Cleanup<br />

Beverage Beverage Container<br />

Container<br />

Type Type<br />

Type<br />

324<br />

29/09/09<br />

2003 2003 2003 2004 2004 2004 2005 2005 2005 2006 2006 2006 2007<br />

2007<br />

Glass Bottles 7,687 11,362 7,194 5,759 5,008<br />

Plastic Bottles 5,246 5,215 3,824 4,799 2,965<br />

Metal Cans 4,946 6,894 3,518 3,959 2,932<br />

Total Total Total<br />

17,879 23,471 23,471 14,430 14,430 14,517 14,517 10,905<br />

10,905<br />

Source: State Of Hawaii <strong>Department</strong> Of Health (2008) Pursuant To Sections 342g-102.5(H), 342g-<br />

114.5(B), And 342g-123, Hawaii Revised Statutes, Requiring The <strong>Department</strong> Of Health To Give A<br />

Report On The Activities Of The Deposit Beverage Container Program, Report To The Twenty-Fifth<br />

Legislature State Of Hawaii 2009, November 2008<br />

Table 16-4: Percentage <strong>of</strong> Total Debris Collected During Cleanup<br />

Beverage Beverage Bottles Bottles & & & Cans Cans 2003 2003 2004 2004 2005 2005 2006 2006 2007<br />

2007<br />

Glass, Glass, Glass, Metal, Metal, & & Plastic Plastic 15.9% 14.5% 12.3% 8.7% 6.7%<br />

Source: State Of Hawaii <strong>Department</strong> Of Health (2008) Pursuant To Sections 342g-102.5(H), 342g-<br />

114.5(B), And 342g-123, Hawaii Revised Statutes, Requiring The <strong>Department</strong> Of Health To Give A<br />

Report On The Activities Of The Deposit Beverage Container Program, Report To The Twenty-Fifth<br />

Legislature State Of Hawaii 2009, November 2008<br />

The report notes:<br />

While there appears to be a downward trend in the number <strong>of</strong> bottles and<br />

cans found at beaches, beverage containers, along with associated caps and<br />

lids, continue to be a large portion <strong>of</strong> beach litter. This is why it is important to<br />

continue to place a deposit on beverage containers to decrease the<br />

temptation to litter and increase the incentive to recycle.<br />

A somewhat interesting feature <strong>of</strong> the Hawaii data is that they show that the problem<br />

is not simply land related. Indeed, beverage containers appear to be (relatively) more<br />

problematic in underwater cleanups (see Table 16-5).<br />

Regarding plastics in particular, a UNEP report notes the prevalence <strong>of</strong> plastic bottles,<br />

caps and bags among the key forms <strong>of</strong> marine litter giving rise to increasingly serious<br />

problems at sea. Evidently, in the marine environment, it is the longevity and potential<br />

Activities Of The Deposit Beverage Container Program, Report To The Twenty-Fifth Legislature State Of<br />

Hawaii 2009, November 2008.


harm caused by plastics in the marine environment that makes them <strong>of</strong> particular<br />

concern. 356<br />

Table 16-5: Top 5 Debris Items Collected During the 2007 Cleanup<br />

Land Land Cleanups Cleanups Only Only<br />

Number Number <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Debris Debris Items<br />

Items<br />

325<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Percent Percent <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

Collected<br />

Collected<br />

1. Cigarettes & Filters 72,053 44.7%<br />

2. Caps & Lids 21,210 13.1%<br />

3. Food Wrappers and Containers 16,554 10.3%<br />

4. Beverage Containers (glass, metal, plastic) 10,505 6.5%<br />

5. Cups, Plates, and Utensils 7,331 4.5%<br />

Underwater Underwater Underwater Cleanups Cleanups Cleanups Only Only Only<br />

Number Number Number <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Debris Debris Debris Items<br />

Items<br />

Percent Percent Percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

Collected<br />

Collected<br />

1. Fishing Line 1081 54%<br />

2. Beverage Containers (glass, metal) 393 19.6%<br />

3. Cigarettes, Filters, & Cigar Tips 248 12.3%<br />

4. Food Wrappers and Containers 55 2.7%<br />

5. Caps & Lids 39 1.9%<br />

Source: State Of Hawaii <strong>Department</strong> Of Health (2008) Pursuant To Sections 342g-102.5(H), 342g-<br />

114.5(B), And 342g-123, Hawaii Revised Statutes, Requiring The <strong>Department</strong> Of Health To Give A<br />

Report On The Activities Of The Deposit Beverage Container Program, Report To The Twenty-Fifth<br />

Legislature State Of Hawaii 2009, November 2008<br />

A study undertaken in Australia suggested that deposit schemes were likely to be the<br />

most effective policy option for reducing litter amongst those considered for<br />

improving recycling: 357<br />

356 Ljubomir Jeftic, Seba Sheavly, and Ellik Adler (2009) Marine Litter: A Global Challenge, Report for<br />

UNEP, April 2009,<br />

http://www.unep.org/regionalseas/marinelitter/publications/docs/Marine_Litter_A_Global_Challenge.<br />

pdf<br />

357 BDA Group (2009) Beverage Container Investigation, Report for the EPHC beverage Container<br />

Working Group, March 2009.


326<br />

29/09/09<br />

A national CDS [container deposit scheme] is expected to provide the greatest<br />

reduction in overall litter levels, with the potential to provide a 6% reduction in<br />

the total national litter count and a 19% reduction in the total national litter<br />

volume.<br />

Finally, there is another way in which removal <strong>of</strong> used beverage containers from litter<br />

could contribute to cleaner streets. To the extent that beverage containers are<br />

relatively voluminous items, then their removal from litter bins would leave more room<br />

for other waste. The CPRE’s Litterbugs report reports that 91% <strong>of</strong> the public believe<br />

that increasing the number <strong>of</strong> bins is the most effective way <strong>of</strong> reducing litter. 358 An<br />

equivalent approach might be to free up space in existing bins. The report cites the<br />

New York bottle bill as reducing container litter by 70-80%. Clean-up costs, as well as<br />

landfill costs, were reduced. The scheme enjoys solid public support (84% <strong>of</strong> voters in<br />

2004) and so has been extended in 2009 to cover non-carbonated drinks, which<br />

make up 27% <strong>of</strong> beverage sales.<br />

16.6.4 Other Benefits<br />

It has been suggested that deposit refund schemes are one way to increase materials<br />

recovery, and can give the best environmental benefits, but that they may be<br />

expensive to implement. Arguably they therefore suit cases in which it is important<br />

from a safety or environmental standpoint not to let materials go unrecovered such<br />

as lead acid batteries or empty pesticide containers. However, the differential<br />

externalities associated with recycling materials as opposed to discarding them in<br />

refuse, are not insignificant in the case <strong>of</strong> packaging. We calculate, for example, that<br />

these may be <strong>of</strong> the order €723 per tonne for aluminium, €111 per tonne for steel,<br />

€150-200 for plastic and €25 per tonne for glass (the higher values for plastic relate<br />

to the effects <strong>of</strong> incineration <strong>of</strong> plastic as opposed to its landfilling). In other words,<br />

these benefits are non-trivial, though they have to be set in context against the costs<br />

<strong>of</strong> collection.<br />

In countries or states where deposit refund schemes have worked in the past, they<br />

are <strong>of</strong>ten popular with the public, helping to gain impetus for the recycling initiative.<br />

For example, there are movements in a number <strong>of</strong> states in Australia and the USA to<br />

implement these schemes.<br />

16.6.5 Implications for Transport<br />

Perchards suggest that in Ireland, introducing a deposit scheme would be<br />

unfavourable from an environmental point <strong>of</strong> view partly owing to duplication in<br />

logistics: 359<br />

358 A. Lewis, P. Turton and T. Sweetman (2009) Litterbugs How to Deal with the Problem <strong>of</strong> Littering,<br />

Report for CPRE, March 2009.<br />

359 G. Bevington (2008) A Deposit and Refund Scheme in Ireland, Report commissioned by Repak Ltd.,<br />

September 2008.


327<br />

Deposit containers would be transported separately for recycling from other<br />

packaging. That would mean additional trucks, with increased energy and<br />

carbon impacts. One set <strong>of</strong> trucks would collect containers from retailers and<br />

another would transport packaging waste collected from the existing bring<br />

and kerbside system. Deposit containers would have to be kept separate from<br />

other packaging. It may sometimes be possible to collect both together, as<br />

deposit packs would have to be in sealed containers, but collection contracts<br />

would be awarded separately for each stream, so this arrangement would<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten not be possible.<br />

This argument is unconvincing and shows little comprehension <strong>of</strong> the factors<br />

affecting collection logistics. Currently, in Ireland, much <strong>of</strong> the collection <strong>of</strong> dry<br />

recyclables makes use <strong>of</strong> ‘brown bin’ collections. The removal <strong>of</strong> low bulk density<br />

beverage containers (plastic and cans) from the collected waste stream would have<br />

the effect <strong>of</strong> freeing up volume on recycling vehicles, improving the logistics for the<br />

existing collection schemes.<br />

Given that:<br />

� the logistics <strong>of</strong> picking up relatively large quantities per pick-up from specific<br />

collection points would be favourable;<br />

� the absence <strong>of</strong> a need for sorting at a dedicated sorting facility (with its own<br />

energy demand); and<br />

� the likely very low loss rates in the recycling process because <strong>of</strong> the presegregated<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> the material,<br />

then the argument made would appear to amount to pure speculation, based upon a<br />

worst case scenario in which there is no effect on the logistics <strong>of</strong> the pre-existing<br />

system, even when low bulk density materials are removed from that collection.<br />

Furthermore, if the recovery <strong>of</strong> containers through a deposit scheme is very high,<br />

arguably, there is no need at all for a ‘duplicate’ scheme. Indeed, this closely<br />

approximates to the Danish approach.<br />

We make similar points below regarding an attempt to understand the cost<br />

implications <strong>of</strong> such an approach.<br />

16.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The costs <strong>of</strong> implementing deposit-refund schemes is a particularly murky area for<br />

analysis, and a crucial one for understanding the potential attractiveness or otherwise<br />

<strong>of</strong> such schemes.<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> theoretical economic studies have indicated that deposit systems are<br />

more cost-effective than other methods <strong>of</strong> reducing waste disposal, such as<br />

traditional forms <strong>of</strong> regulations, recycling subsidies, or advance disposal fees (ADF)<br />

alone. The study by Palmer et al. concluded that a 10% reduction in waste disposal<br />

would cost $45 per ton <strong>of</strong> waste reduced under a deposit system, compared to $85<br />

per ton under advance disposal fees and $98 per ton under recycling subsidies.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


However, the study noted that the relatively high administrative costs <strong>of</strong> a real world<br />

deposit refund system could outweigh these cost savings. 360<br />

Evidence on the administrative costs <strong>of</strong> bottle bills is sparse, with clear comparisons<br />

between schemes hindered by differing scheme structures and study methodologies.<br />

Traditional bottle bills, such as in Massachusetts, that require retailers to pay refunds<br />

to consumers, sort containers by brand name, and store containers until bottlers<br />

collect them are likely to be the most expensive to administer. Ackerman et al. found<br />

that this deposit/refund system costs 2.3 cents per container, which corresponds to<br />

approximately $320/tonne for a typical steel can. 361 Other designs for<br />

deposit/refunds may result in lower average admin costs, such as California’s bottle<br />

bill which has administrative costs <strong>of</strong> only 0.2 cents per container, or $28/ton for<br />

steel cans.<br />

Industry suggests a net cost <strong>of</strong> system operation per container sold <strong>of</strong> €0.004 in<br />

Alberta, €0.005 in British Columbia, €0.01 in Finland, €0.011 in Sweden, and €0.014<br />

in Saskatchewan. 362 The same source compares such costs against Green Dot<br />

producer responsibility schemes, indicating that Fost Plus (Belgium) claims a cost <strong>of</strong><br />

€0.002 for a can, and €0.0135 for a PET bottle. In Germany, the costs <strong>of</strong> DSD are<br />

quoted as €0.009 for a steel can, €0.011 for an aluminium can, €0.021 for a glass<br />

bottle, and €0.05 for a PET bottle. However, these figures should be interpreted with<br />

caution as it is not at all clear that similar cost streams are being detailed in every<br />

case.<br />

It is also incomplete to talk simply about scheme costs when the different schemes<br />

are bringing about different levels <strong>of</strong> recycling. Thus, varying levels <strong>of</strong> benefit are<br />

being realised from these different schemes, in terms <strong>of</strong> both litter reduction and<br />

savings in wider environmental and social costs. A full cost-benefit analysis would<br />

take into account these aspects, comparing them to a baseline or counterfactual<br />

case.<br />

An ex-ante cost-benefit analysis has recently been undertaken in New Zealand,<br />

suggesting that the imposition <strong>of</strong> a deposit/refund scheme would deliver a net cost to<br />

society. 363 This was against a baseline <strong>of</strong> an existing kerbside recycling scheme. In<br />

effect the analysis was investigating the marginal costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> such a<br />

scheme, taking into account the impact that diversion <strong>of</strong> materials would have upon<br />

the cost-effectiveness <strong>of</strong> existing municipal recycling. An analysis with a baseline <strong>of</strong><br />

no recycling could be expected to deliver a more positive result, but again this would<br />

360 K. Palmer, H. Sigman and M. Walls (1997) The Cost <strong>of</strong> Reducing Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong>, Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental Economics and <strong>Management</strong> 33, 128-50.<br />

361 Frank Ackerman, Dmitri Cavander, John Stutz, and Brian Zuckerman (1995) Preliminary Analysis:<br />

The Costs and Benefits <strong>of</strong> Bottle Bills, Draft report to U.S. EPA/Office <strong>of</strong> Solid <strong>Waste</strong> and Emergency<br />

Response, Boston, Mass.: Tellus Institute.<br />

362 Communication with TOMRA.<br />

363 Covec Report (2008) Potential Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation (Solids) Bill: Update Report,<br />

Report for Packaging Council <strong>of</strong> New Zealand, May 2008, http://www.pca.org.au/uploads/00548.pdf<br />

328<br />

29/09/09


have to be compared with the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> the implementation <strong>of</strong> alternative<br />

recycling approaches.<br />

The Covec report referred to above reports that the likely cost <strong>of</strong> implementing a<br />

deposit refund scheme in New Zealand (which has a similar population size to<br />

Ireland), to increase recycling and reduce waste by approximately 45,000 tonnes,<br />

would be between NZ$48 and NZ$90 million (approximately €22 million to €41<br />

million at 13 th October 2008 exchange rates). To give an indication <strong>of</strong> the size <strong>of</strong> the<br />

market for which this calculation was done, the base <strong>of</strong> materials production and<br />

consumption is shown in Table 16-6.<br />

Table 16-6: New Zealand Production, Consumption and Recycling (without deposit<br />

refund scheme), 2006<br />

Material<br />

Material<br />

Materials<br />

Materials<br />

Production<br />

Production<br />

(tonnes)<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Consumption<br />

Consumption<br />

(tonnes)<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Collection<br />

Collection<br />

(tonnes)<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Collection ollection as as % % <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

consumption<br />

consumption<br />

packaging<br />

packaging<br />

accord accord target<br />

target<br />

Aluminium 7,895 6,270 3,900 62% 65%<br />

Glass 128,110 208,240 109,860 53% 55%<br />

Paper 492,300 336,500 256,200 76% 70%<br />

Plastics 136,079 156,359 34,891 22% 23%<br />

Steel 44,765 21,340 12,245 57% 43%<br />

Tota Total Tota Total<br />

l 809,149 728,709 417,096 57%<br />

Source: NZ Packaging Council<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> cost comparison with alternative collection routes, bearing in mind the<br />

caveats previously mentioned, a 1998 study helps to indicate the relative costs <strong>of</strong><br />

different recycling systems. The authors found that the costs <strong>of</strong> collection, sorting and<br />

recycling a 33cl aluminium can were (in US dollars): $0.0161(Germany), $0.0105<br />

(Sweden) and $0.0345 (Switzerland). These costs related to Germany’s kerbside<br />

recycling, Sweden’s deposit refund scheme and Switzerland’s bring system. However,<br />

caution must be applied in comparing these estimates, as different market forces and<br />

economic factors are at work in the three different countries. 364<br />

The costs attached to redeeming the deposits impact retailers. Costs are in the form<br />

<strong>of</strong> capital to purchase RVMs or space set aside for returned containers. ERM’s 2008<br />

report for Defra reports that Germany’s 21,000 RVMs were installed at an average<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> £11,000. 365 In some countries, help is given by the producers and importers,<br />

either to encourage use <strong>of</strong> RVMs or compensate for the loss <strong>of</strong> retail space.<br />

364 N. Tojo, T. Lindhqvist and G. Davis (2001) OECD Seminar on Extended Producer Responsibility,<br />

EPR: Programme Implementation and Assessment, Seminar for the OECD, December 2001.<br />

365 ERM (2008), <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Packaging Deposit Systems for the UK, Report for DEFRA, December 2008,<br />

accessed from http://randd.defra.gov.uk/Document.aspx?Document=WR1203_7722_FRP.pdf<br />

329<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The German deposit scheme is recognized as an expensive scheme. Perchards<br />

note: 366<br />

330<br />

29/09/09<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the small importers in our survey reported that DPG participation was<br />

very expensive, far more than participation in DSD. These costs had a knockon<br />

effect on the retail price <strong>of</strong> the drink.<br />

Some also reported administrative problems, such as that DPG was slow to<br />

refund deposit monies and that it had changed its terms and conditions three<br />

times last year. Some other importers indicated similar problems, but put<br />

these down to ‘teething troubles’, and said that things were now operating<br />

more smoothly.<br />

Some importers told us that their customers are expressing a preference for<br />

refillables, and so these importers are now considering switching to refillables.<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> these issues may relate specifically to the way DPG operates, but<br />

much <strong>of</strong> the expense is inherent in any clearing system for deposits, and<br />

these costs inevitably bear more heavily on low-volume operators.<br />

Imported speciality products have to compete in a highly price-sensitive<br />

market in which the deposit on non-refillables might be twice the basic price<br />

<strong>of</strong> the product. For example, in REWE, which is not classified as a discounter,<br />

we bought a bottle <strong>of</strong> mineral water for € 0.12 (plus €0.25 deposit). In a REAL<br />

hypermarket and in the discounter Penny, we bought beer for € 0.29 (plus<br />

€0.25 deposit). Cans <strong>of</strong> Faxe beer imported from Denmark cost €0.55 (plus<br />

€0.25 deposit) at the traditional supermarket Edeka.<br />

Where imported speciality beers were on sale, which was predominantly in<br />

department store food halls, we found that the bottles were <strong>of</strong>ten sold as<br />

refillables. During our telephone survey <strong>of</strong> importers, we were told that<br />

participation in DPG is simply too expensive for the small quantities <strong>of</strong> each<br />

beer imported by each company. To recover the cost <strong>of</strong> registration, the retail<br />

price <strong>of</strong> the beer would have to increase by around €0.30 per bottle, which is<br />

more than the total price excluding deposit <strong>of</strong> standard German beers. One<br />

importer told us that it had lost around half its customers since the deposit<br />

was first imposed. Marking the bottles as refillable and charging only an<br />

€0.08 deposit reduces the perceived price by €0.17. Even so, we paid € 1.99<br />

for a bottle <strong>of</strong> Spendrups beer from Sweden (which no deposit was charged<br />

on, for some reason) and € 2.49 for Asahi and Quilmes, from Karstadt<br />

department stores.<br />

In a more recent report, Perchards add, regarding the German system: 367<br />

DPG, the system operators, commented in May 2008 that the cost per<br />

container is three times as much as household-based collection.<br />

366 Perchards (2007) Study on Factual Implementation <strong>of</strong> a Nationwide Take-back System in Germany<br />

After 1 May 2006, Final Report, 14 February 2007.<br />

367 G. Bevington (2008) A Deposit and Refund Scheme in Ireland, Report commissioned by Repak Ltd.,<br />

September 2008.


Of particular interest are some <strong>of</strong> the comments relating the costs to those <strong>of</strong> the<br />

DSD system. Even here, however, some caution is required since fees do not always<br />

replicate the actual ‘costs’ <strong>of</strong> the system. Furthermore, the effect <strong>of</strong> deposits on<br />

consumer behaviour is not necessarily based upon an assumption regarding the price<br />

inclusive <strong>of</strong> deposits. How consumers take into account the deposit in their<br />

consumption decisions is likely to be a function <strong>of</strong> the ease with which they can<br />

obtain their refund, and possibly, their income status. To the extent that obtaining<br />

refunds is simple and straightforward, the deposit itself might be discounted by<br />

consumers.<br />

One study sought to understand the effects <strong>of</strong> introducing a deposit scheme against<br />

the backdrop <strong>of</strong> an existing kerbside scheme. 368 This study is also referred to by<br />

EUROPEN, who state:<br />

331<br />

Indeed, deposit systems for non-refillable beverage containers risk<br />

undermining the economics <strong>of</strong> collecting other forms <strong>of</strong> packaging through<br />

integral multi-material collection systems for packaging waste (BIO<br />

Intelligence Service 2005). Without the critical mass <strong>of</strong>fered by beverage<br />

containers, the economics <strong>of</strong> integral and multi-material collection systems for<br />

packaging waste are much less favourable. In Germany, about 20% <strong>of</strong> DSD’s<br />

fee income came from packaging which is now part <strong>of</strong> a deposit system<br />

instead.<br />

Imposing a deposit system adds to costs without improving recycling rates.<br />

Multi-material selective collection systems and mandatory deposits both<br />

usually collect about 70% <strong>of</strong> the available material, but industry studies<br />

indicate that whereas multi-material collection costs between EUR 320 and<br />

EUR 770 per tonne, a combination <strong>of</strong> multi-material collection and deposits<br />

costs between EUR 790 and EUR 1200 per tonne.<br />

It is worth stating that the study is not entirely transparent regarding methodology.<br />

However, the costs do not appear to be based upon any detailed logistics modelling,<br />

so the costs per tonne collected from the kerbside scheme do not obviously change<br />

when the mix <strong>of</strong> materials collected changes. The effect <strong>of</strong> this in the schemes<br />

analysed would be to change the collection costs significantly as the bulk <strong>of</strong> materials<br />

collected become paper and card once the deposit scheme is introduced in parallel<br />

(as is suggested it will be). In addition, the sorting costs would change. The study does<br />

not consider the possible effects, in terms <strong>of</strong> cost, <strong>of</strong> a change in littering. This would<br />

be expected to affect costs <strong>of</strong> clean up <strong>of</strong> littering and the costs <strong>of</strong> disposal.<br />

Finally, it should be stated that the study assumes that the introduction <strong>of</strong> a deposit<br />

scheme lowers the overall recycling rate. There appears to be relatively little evidence<br />

to support this, but the study argued this point with reference to US systems. Indeed,<br />

the only reason to believe that this would happen – on the basis <strong>of</strong> the literature -<br />

368 BIO Intelligence Service (2005) Environmental- and Cost-efficiency <strong>of</strong> Household Packaging waste<br />

Collection Systems: Impact <strong>of</strong> a Deposit System on an Existing Multi-material Kerbside Selective<br />

Collection System, Report for APEAL, March 2005.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


would be if the deposit was set very low, or if the scheme was poorly designed.<br />

Neither assumption would be a fair one to make in the nature <strong>of</strong> such a comparison.<br />

Ultimately, the review <strong>of</strong> evidence in the area <strong>of</strong> ‘costs’ highlights a degree <strong>of</strong><br />

polarisation in the ‘debate’ concerning whether beverage packaging should be<br />

collected through deposit refunds or through separate collection systems.<br />

Commentators appear to have taken a position on one side or the other, and have<br />

then sought to select evidence which they believe supports their argument. The<br />

argument is not, however, conclusively won in favour <strong>of</strong> one side or the other, and<br />

indeed, it is surprising that only one study has really sought to examine which system<br />

might be the best, and under what conditions. This is the study by BDA Group.<br />

The study considered the influence <strong>of</strong> the deposit refund scheme on the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

operating recycling services. The study, undertaken in Australia, suggested that<br />

deposit schemes were much the most expensive option for recovering containers (see<br />

Table 16-7 and Figure 16-7. 369<br />

Table 16-7: Net Economic Cost <strong>of</strong> Options (excludes environmental costs and<br />

benefits)<br />

Option Option<br />

Economic Economic cost cost ($ m per annum)<br />

Container deposit system $492.0<br />

Extended kerbside/drop-<strong>of</strong>f $30.4<br />

Public place recovery $5.7<br />

Events recovery $11.2<br />

Hospitality/retail/institutions recovery $1.5<br />

Workplace recovery $5.8<br />

Residual waste processing systems $72.0<br />

Advance disposal fee $42.4<br />

Voluntary glass levy $8.6<br />

Source: BDA Group (2009) Beverage Container Investigation, Report for the EPHC<br />

beverage Container Working Group, March 2009.<br />

369 BDA Group (2009) Beverage Container Investigation, Report for the EPHC beverage Container<br />

Working Group, March 2009.<br />

332<br />

29/09/09


Figure 16-7: Economic Cost per Tonne <strong>of</strong> Packaging Recovered Under Each Option<br />

Source: BDA Group (2009) Beverage Container Investigation, Report for the EPHC beverage Container<br />

Working Group, March 2009.<br />

The study concludes:<br />

333<br />

Direct comparison between CDS and ADF indicates that CDS is only superior if<br />

significant weight is given to litter benefits and little weight given to packaging<br />

other than beverage containers. Sensitivity analysis <strong>of</strong> key design parameters<br />

provides confidence in this finding. Further, the ADF design investigated in this<br />

study focussed on resource recovery, whereas an alternative strategy which<br />

invested at least some ADF revenue on litter reduction programs could be<br />

expected to deliver greater litter benefits.<br />

The study also estimated costs <strong>of</strong> the deposit scheme in South Australia, which it<br />

reported as in Table 16-8, though the model assessed was based upon the<br />

Californian model.<br />

Table 16-8: Indicative Cost and Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the SA CDS Scheme<br />

Scheme Scheme parameter<br />

parameter<br />

Container drop-<strong>of</strong>f 32,000 tonnes<br />

Containers thru kerbside and MRFs 8,000 tonnes<br />

Cost <strong>of</strong> containers thru CDS system $20.44 million<br />

Cost <strong>of</strong> containers thru kerbside and MRFs $ 1.45 million<br />

Nominal cost <strong>of</strong> capital investment $ 0.24 million<br />

Population served thru CDS 1.5 million<br />

Cost Cost per per tonne tonne recovered recovered<br />

$550 per tonne<br />

Cost Cost per per capita capita<br />

$14 $14 to to $15 $15 per per head<br />

head<br />

Source: Recyclers <strong>of</strong> SA & WCS estimates, in BDA Group (2009) Beverage Container Investigation,<br />

Report for the EPHC beverage Container Working Group, March 2009.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


It is important to recognise also that the nature <strong>of</strong> the take-back system in deposit<br />

refund schemes generally lends itself to the delivery <strong>of</strong> higher quality materials from<br />

the waste stream. In the context <strong>of</strong> ongoing issues around the quality <strong>of</strong> materials<br />

extracted for recycling within Ireland, this might be a relevant point. Equally, there are<br />

ways <strong>of</strong> operating kerbside collection systems which are more and less prone to<br />

contamination <strong>of</strong> the materials collected, so deposit schemes are not the only way <strong>of</strong><br />

addressing the issue <strong>of</strong> quality in terms <strong>of</strong> materials collected.<br />

16.8 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> deposit refund schemes has been to reinforce the ongoing<br />

development <strong>of</strong> near infrared sorting techniques. These are increasingly deployed in<br />

reverse vending machines. In addition, the labelling <strong>of</strong> containers in deposit schemes<br />

has developed over time to allow ‘in scheme’ and ‘out <strong>of</strong> scheme’ containers to be<br />

detected.<br />

On the choice <strong>of</strong> distribution method – one-way or refillable – deposit refunds have<br />

been used in some circumstances to maintain the refillable market, though not<br />

always with success. Anderson suggests that Germany used different charges for<br />

single-use and for refillable bottles and found that sales <strong>of</strong> non-refillable containers<br />

dropped by about 60%. 370 He also suggests that refillable PET bottles are<br />

increasingly being used and composite packaging is being substituted with single<br />

material alternatives. However, this outcome refers to systems in place prior to the<br />

most recent experience, which is discussed further in Annex 17.0.<br />

Fee setting for deposit refund schemes has been used, for example in Taiwan, to<br />

discourage certain materials (in particular PVC) and encourage single material<br />

containers.<br />

The technology <strong>of</strong> PET recycling has been stimulated (though arguably by both the<br />

Packaging Directive implementations and deposit-refund schemes). Increasingly PET<br />

bottles can be recycled back into PET bottles, but as there is a loss <strong>of</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> the<br />

end product this cannot be regarded as a closed loop.<br />

16.9 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

Generally, it might be supposed that deposits are small enough that they do not<br />

represent a barrier to purchase, especially given that the refund is normally soon after<br />

purchase, either because the goods are fast-moving consumer goods (like beverages)<br />

or the system is set up to facilitate early refund (e.g. the used lead acid battery has to<br />

be returned within 30 days <strong>of</strong> buying a new one to collect the refund). However, some<br />

schemes, such as the German scheme, operate with high levels <strong>of</strong> deposit. The effect<br />

on the consumer market is not clear, but evidently, consumers who are more cash<br />

poor may be encouraged to purchase containers without deposits, especially if these<br />

exist, and if obtaining the refund is not straightforward.<br />

370 Robert C. Anderson (2004) The United States Experience with Economic Incentives for Protecting<br />

the Environment, Report for US EPA, Nov 2004.<br />

334<br />

29/09/09


One <strong>of</strong> the concerns within Europe has been the distributional impact across<br />

domestic and foreign producers <strong>of</strong> beverages. Several documents highlight the<br />

potential for deposit refund schemes to place foreign producers at a disadvantage<br />

relative to domestic producers, the argument being that there is a protectionist slant<br />

to deposit refund systems, and that they fragment the Single Market. In May 2009,<br />

the European Commission issued a Communication on Beverage packaging, deposit<br />

systems and the free movement <strong>of</strong> goods: 371<br />

335<br />

While regulatory steering measures taken at Member State level in order to<br />

introduce systems for the reuse <strong>of</strong> beverage packaging may serve<br />

environmental goals, they also have the potential to divide the internal<br />

market. For market operators engaged in activities in several Member States<br />

these systems <strong>of</strong>ten make it more difficult to take advantage <strong>of</strong> business<br />

opportunities within the internal market. Instead <strong>of</strong> selling the same product in<br />

the same packaging in different markets, they are required to adapt their<br />

packaging to the requirements <strong>of</strong> each individual Member State, which usually<br />

leads to additional costs.[…]<br />

Past experience and ongoing cases show that the adoption <strong>of</strong> unilateral<br />

measures in different Member States still poses problems. In particular,<br />

infringement procedures in the beverage sector have shown that national<br />

measures can lead to distortions <strong>of</strong> competition and, in some cases, to the<br />

partitioning <strong>of</strong> the internal market, which runs counter to the internal market<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> Directive 94/62/EC.<br />

The Communication is presented as a list <strong>of</strong> ‘do’s’ and ‘don’ts’ for Member States to<br />

assist them in the design <strong>of</strong> their policies in such a way that problems in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

the internal market are minimised or eliminated. It is important to note, however, that<br />

what the Communication very clearly avoids saying is that deposit refund schemes<br />

are not legal. It merely highlights the fact that the design <strong>of</strong> such systems should be<br />

carefully considered, particularly with regard to their effect on the workings <strong>of</strong> the<br />

internal market. Moreover, it recognises that such schemes can be justified even<br />

where they may be construed as barriers to trade:<br />

The fact that they would qualify as a trade barrier, however, does not prevent<br />

these national provisions from being justified on grounds relating to the<br />

protection <strong>of</strong> the environment. According to the Court <strong>of</strong> Justice, a deposit and<br />

return system may increase the proportion <strong>of</strong> empty packaging returned, and<br />

at the same time lead to a more targeted sorting <strong>of</strong> packaging waste.<br />

Moreover, it may help prevent littering, as it gives consumers an incentive to<br />

return empty packaging.15 Finally, ins<strong>of</strong>ar as those national provisions<br />

encourage the producers or distributors concerned to have recourse to<br />

reusable packaging, they contribute towards a general reduction in the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong>, which is a general goal in environmental policy.<br />

In In practice, practice, practice, this this means means that that Member Member States States are are allowed allowed to to introduce<br />

introduce<br />

371 European Commission (2009) Communication from the Commission on Beverage packaging,<br />

deposit systems and the free movement <strong>of</strong> goods, C(2009) 3447 final Brussels 8 th May 2009.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


336<br />

29/09/09<br />

mandatory mandatory mandatory deposi deposit deposi deposit<br />

t systems systems if, if, on on the the basis basis <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the the individual individual Member Member State's State's<br />

State's<br />

discretion, this this is is considered considered necessary necessary necessary for for environmental environmental reasons. reasons.<br />

reasons.<br />

It goes on to note, however, the need for a balanced and proportionate approach:<br />

If a Member State opts for a mandatory deposit and return system, it must<br />

nevertheless observe certain requirements in order to ensure that a fair<br />

balance is struck between environmental objectives and internal market<br />

needs. In view <strong>of</strong> the additional burden on imported products, such systems<br />

must take note <strong>of</strong> the specific situation and must use means which do not go<br />

beyond what is necessary for the purpose envisaged.<br />

It then describes approaches considered to be appropriate in the case where such<br />

schemes are introduced. This advice appears sound in the light <strong>of</strong> the considerable<br />

opposition which such schemes have engendered in respect to internal market<br />

effects.<br />

There is some evidence to suggest that deposit refund systems, whilst they may<br />

engender complaints from some industry sectors, can be popular with the public. The<br />

Covec report referenced above quotes the following surveys: over 95% <strong>of</strong> South<br />

Australians contacted in a 1993 telephone survey supported refundable deposits on<br />

beverage containers; a 1998 study found that 96% <strong>of</strong> British Columbians thought that<br />

container deposits were a good idea.<br />

16.10 Complementary Policies<br />

Packaging taxes, product levies or product bans can be used to influence the<br />

materials chosen by manufacturers, to ensure that efficient recycling <strong>of</strong> the collected<br />

items can take place. Producer responsibility systems are also relevant, with some<br />

countries, such as Denmark, effectively discharging their obligations through a<br />

combination <strong>of</strong> taxes and deposit refunds.<br />

16.11 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

To the consumer this may appear to be a zero net price influence when the refund is<br />

awarded. However, deposit refund systems are not costless to implement and<br />

administer so this cost will be borne ultimately by the consumer. In principle, deposit<br />

refunds are, as discussed above, taken to be efficient policy measures, or at least,<br />

they have the potential to be so. They act as an advanced disposal fee coupled to a<br />

recycling subsidy for the returnee. The level at which deposits are set, however,<br />

influences whether the mechanism is genuinely efficient from the economic<br />

perspective.<br />

16.12 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Deposit refund systems are effectively self-policing to a large extent, as there is an<br />

incentive to return the used product. However, in Denmark, one type <strong>of</strong> fraud that<br />

has been tried has been to copy the product code onto a non-returnable empty bottle


(e.g. brought from Germany) so that the reverse vending machine (RVM) will accept<br />

the bottle and pay out the refund. Dansk Retursystem A/S has developed systems to<br />

prevent such fraud in Denmark. 372 Firstly, for refillable (more rigid) bottles the RVM<br />

matches the shape with the product code before paying, and secondly, for one-way<br />

packaging, a special ink has been developed for the product code so that it is not<br />

possible to copy onto another (non-refundable) bottle.<br />

The German system was particularly at risk <strong>of</strong> fraud given following conditions:<br />

337<br />

� The high deposit (25 Euro cents);<br />

� Nine bordering countries<br />

� The anonymous environment <strong>of</strong> the reverse vending machine<br />

� Not necessarily any differentiation <strong>of</strong> shape or weight between deposit and<br />

non-deposit containers<br />

Therefore, in addition to a bar code, a ‘DPG’ sticker is added and the combination <strong>of</strong><br />

the two is used to recognise a valid deposit container.<br />

16.13 Lessons Learned<br />

Lessons from international implementations include:<br />

� Deposit refund policies can encourage both reuse, and as such waste<br />

prevention, and recycling. They can incentivise this through encouraging the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> refillable container systems, which can be subject to lower or zero<br />

deposits than on one-way containers;<br />

� Care has to be taken in designing deposit refund schemes in Europe such that<br />

they are proportionate in their effect, and do not effectively become trade<br />

barriers, or obstacles to the free movement <strong>of</strong> goods, in ways which are<br />

disproportionate relative to the environmental outcome being sought;<br />

� The German experience has been that a mandatory deposit has not halted the<br />

decline in refillable and environmentally favourable containers (see Annex<br />

17.0);<br />

� Rates <strong>of</strong> take back can be extremely high, but as expected, this return rate is<br />

sensitive to the deposit rate;<br />

� The quality <strong>of</strong> material captured under a deposit refund scheme tends to be<br />

high relative to what is obtained though kerbside recycling schemes, especially<br />

for PET. This is potentially significant for Ireland in the current context where<br />

market prices have declined, and where reprocessors will, as demand falls, be<br />

seeking to turn away low quality materials before high quality ones;<br />

� There must be sufficient collection points to ensure a convenient endconsumer<br />

experience;<br />

372 Personal Communication with Anker Andersen a/s, 11 September 2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


338<br />

� Deposit refund schemes can reduce the prevalence <strong>of</strong> litter;<br />

� Issues associated with cross-border purchases need to be considered in<br />

scheme design. This is likely to be important in the Irish context, not least as a<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> recent exchange rate movements;<br />

� An appropriate labelling scheme or other system may be to deal with free<br />

riders;<br />

� Refillable containers may lead to greater distances being travelled for<br />

returning bottles, so requiring refillables to be used may lead to claims that<br />

the market is being structured in such a way as to place imported goods at a<br />

disadvantage; and<br />

� There is little clear information regarding what the costs <strong>of</strong> scheme<br />

implementation might be in the Irish context. Views appear to be polarised<br />

regarding the costs <strong>of</strong> introducing such a scheme, and few studies from the<br />

available literature would appear to enable one to confidently assert that the<br />

approach incurs costs well above the additional benefits which might be<br />

derived. There are, however, indications that such schemes would need to be<br />

designed with great care to ensure costs were aligned with the hoped for<br />

benefits.<br />

16.14 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

One sensitivity that any state system in Europe needs to take into consideration is the<br />

issue <strong>of</strong> free trade. The OECD reports that deposit-refund systems will create barriers<br />

to trade: 373<br />

� if the initial deposits are high compared to the value <strong>of</strong> the goods;<br />

� if foreign producers see that the costs <strong>of</strong> participating in a co-operative<br />

retrieval and recycling scheme are out <strong>of</strong> proportion to their market share;<br />

� if non-refillable containers are an important condition for the competitiveness<br />

<strong>of</strong> imports;<br />

� if they are applied only to certain types <strong>of</strong> containers or packaging which are<br />

primarily used for imported products; or<br />

� if they are applied in a fashion which is discriminatory or which unduly favours<br />

domestic products.<br />

As well as governmental resolve to force industry to accept the extra costs that<br />

deposit refund schemes will entail, sufficient infrastructural provision is necessary to<br />

cope with increased / altered collection and reprocessing requirements. As stated<br />

above, this has also been a key concern within Europe: 374<br />

373 OECD (1993) Applying Economic Instruments to Packaging <strong>Waste</strong>: Practical Issues for Product<br />

Charges and Deposit Refund Systems, Paris: OECD.<br />

374 European Commission (2009) Communication from the Commission on Beverage packaging,<br />

deposit systems and the free movement <strong>of</strong> goods, C(2009) 3447 final Brussels 8 th May 2009.<br />

29/09/09


Another pre-requisite, partly because <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> the complaints which deposit<br />

refunds have drawn in respect <strong>of</strong> their implementation, is the political will to take the<br />

policy through to implementation. Schemes will require co-operation <strong>of</strong> various<br />

parties, including the public, so that engagement with the relevant parties is<br />

necessary.<br />

339<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


17.0 Deposit Refund Scheme - Germany<br />

17.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Mandatory deposits were introduced in Germany in January 2003 for non-refillable<br />

containers (cans, glass and plastic bottles) for water, beer and carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t<br />

drinks. On 28 th <strong>of</strong> May 2005 the 3 rd amendment <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Ordinance came<br />

into force. 375 It simplifies the deposit on cans (regulated in Art. 9 <strong>of</strong> the Packaging<br />

Ordinance). In December 2004 the European Court <strong>of</strong> Justice confirmed that the<br />

compulsory deposit scheme is, in principle, compatible with EU law. 376 This decision<br />

paved the way for the new provisions.<br />

The new provisions were implemented in two steps. The first step came into force on<br />

the 28th <strong>of</strong> May 2005: There is only one standard deposit <strong>of</strong> 25 euro cents for all<br />

sizes <strong>of</strong> containers ranging from 0.1 litres to 3 litres.<br />

Since May 2006, the third amendment to the German Packaging Ordinance has been<br />

in force – with an extended scope <strong>of</strong> deposits being levied on non-returnable<br />

beverage packages and the simultaneous launch <strong>of</strong> a nationwide standardised<br />

clearing system. The deposit was extended to all one-way drinks packaging which is<br />

not “ecologically advantageous” and contains the following beverages (see Article 9,<br />

paragraph 2 <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Ordinance):<br />

340<br />

� Beer (including alcohol-free beer) and mixed drinks containing beer,<br />

� Mineral water, spring waters, table waters and remedial waters,<br />

� Carbonated and non-carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks (specifically lemonades, including<br />

cola drinks, fizzy drinks, bitter drinks and ice-tea). Fruit juices, fruit nectars,<br />

vegetable juices, vegetable nectars, drinks with a minimum <strong>of</strong> 50 per cent milk<br />

or other milk-derived products, dietetic drinks within the meaning <strong>of</strong> Article 1<br />

(1) <strong>of</strong> the Ordinance on Dietetic Foodstuffs (Diätverordnung) and mixes <strong>of</strong> such<br />

drinks shall not be s<strong>of</strong>t drinks within the meaning <strong>of</strong> sentence 1.<br />

� Mixed alcoholic drinks<br />

29/09/09<br />

• produced using<br />

o products which are subject to spirits tax under Article 130 (1) <strong>of</strong><br />

the Federal Spirits Monopoly Act (Branntweinmonopolgesetz) or<br />

fermentation alcohol made from beer, wine or wine-like<br />

products, including in processed form, which has been<br />

processed using technology which no longer meets the<br />

375 Ordinance <strong>of</strong> 21 August 1998 (Federal Law Gazette I p. 2379); as amended by Article 1 Third<br />

Amending Ordinance <strong>of</strong> 24 May 2005 (Federal Law Gazette I <strong>of</strong> 27 May 2005, p. 1407); last<br />

amendment by Fifth Ordinance <strong>of</strong> 2 April 2008.<br />

376 ECJ from 14.12.2004, C-463/01 (Mineralwässer); ECJ from 14.12.2004, C-309/02 (Radlberger).


341<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

requirements for good manufacturing practice and containing<br />

less than 15 per cent alcohol or<br />

• containing less than 50 per cent wine or wine-like products, including in<br />

processed form.<br />

Consequently, wine, milk and fruit-juices, for example, continue to be exempted from<br />

the non-returnables deposit, as do packages that under the German Packaging<br />

Ordinance are classified as ecologically advantageous. In Article 3, paragraph 4, the<br />

Packaging Ordinance legally defines the following drinks packaging as “ecologically<br />

advantageous”:<br />

� Drinks carton packaging (brick packs, gable-top cartons),<br />

� Drinks packaging in the form <strong>of</strong> polyethylene bags,<br />

� Stand-up bags.<br />

Furthermore so-called “individual solutions” (major discounters such as Aldi, Lidl and<br />

Plus) were discontinued. Under the "individual solutions", discounters only had to take<br />

back one-way drinks packaging sold by their own sales chain. Since 2006, stores that<br />

sell drink cans, glass or plastic bottles are obliged to take back corresponding<br />

packaging from other drinks manufacturers as well. Empty one-way bottles and cans<br />

can be returned to any outlet where one-way packaging is sold. This regulation<br />

effectively promotes the development <strong>of</strong> a uniform nationwide return system and this<br />

is now in the process <strong>of</strong> being established.<br />

As from May 2006 the deposit is compulsory for all one-way packaging from 0.1 litres<br />

to 3 litres that is not “ecologically advantageous”. This includes all packaging <strong>of</strong> beer,<br />

mineral water and carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks which are already subject to deposit. A<br />

deposit was also introduced for non-carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks and alcoholic mixed<br />

drinks, notably alcopops. The deposit is compulsory for ice tea cans just as it is for<br />

coke or beer cans. Packaging <strong>of</strong> juices, milk and wine as well as the supposedly less<br />

ecologically damaging packaging such as drink cartons, polyethylene tubular bags<br />

and stand-up bags remain exempted from the deposit. The German Parliament<br />

decides in the Packaging ordinance based, inter alia, on scientific studies <strong>of</strong> which<br />

type <strong>of</strong> packaging is ecologically advantageous and which is not.<br />

17.2 Reason for the <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The main reason for the introduction <strong>of</strong> the deposit on cans in Germany was the<br />

failure to achieve the targeted reuse rate (72 % <strong>of</strong> the packaging <strong>of</strong> beverages had to<br />

be reusable) over a number <strong>of</strong> years.<br />

As a first step towards the current situation, the necessary regulation (Art. 9 Para 2 <strong>of</strong><br />

the Packaging Ordinance from 1998) came into force and the deposit on cans was<br />

introduced. With this legal regulation in place, the deposit on cans now became<br />

independent <strong>of</strong> compliance with the target reuse rate. Furthermore it was the<br />

objective <strong>of</strong> the former German government to promote reusable drinks packaging as<br />

a way <strong>of</strong> implementing a deepening <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility and at the same time,<br />

strengthening the promotion <strong>of</strong> the saving <strong>of</strong> natural resources by waste prevention.<br />

The following timetable outlines the key dates associated with the policy’s<br />

introduction:


342<br />

� 1991 1991: 1991 1991 The Packaging Ordinance came into force (the ordinance included a<br />

target reuse rate <strong>of</strong> 72 % for the promotion (and protection) <strong>of</strong> reusable<br />

beverage packaging as environmentally advantageous packaging; the<br />

Ordinance stated that if the rate at which beverages were filled in reusable<br />

packages fell below 72%, a deposit would become compulsory for several<br />

types <strong>of</strong> one-way packaging). Today the Ordinance aims to increase, to at least<br />

80 per cent, the share <strong>of</strong> beverages sold in reusable drinks packaging and<br />

“ecologically advantageous one-way drinks packaging”;<br />

� 1998 1998: 1998 1998 amendment <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Ordinance;<br />

� 1997 1997-2002 1997 1997 2002 2002: 2002 repeated non-achievement <strong>of</strong> the reuse rate;<br />

� April April 2002 2002: 2002 assessment <strong>of</strong> costs for the introduction <strong>of</strong> the deposit on cans;<br />

� January January January 2003/October 2003/October 2003/October 2003 2003: 2003 2003 introduction <strong>of</strong> the one-way deposit in two steps;<br />

� May May May 2005 2005: 2005 2005 The Ordinance was adopted by the German Parliament;<br />

� May May 2005 2005: 2005 In order to simplify the regulations on one-way drink packaging, a<br />

new Packaging Ordinance came into force (third amendment <strong>of</strong> the packaging<br />

ordinance);<br />

� January January 2006 2006: 2006 2006 The fourth amendment <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Ordinance came into<br />

force (implementation <strong>of</strong> the Directive 2004/12/EU – packaging and waste<br />

packages);<br />

� May May May 2006 2006: 2006 The deposit became compulsory for non-carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks<br />

and alcohol-mixed drinks (alcopops);<br />

� April April 2009 2009: 2009 The fifth amendment <strong>of</strong> the Packaging Ordinance will come into<br />

force, but this will not alter the regulations for one-way drink packaging.<br />

17.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

For monitoring and measurement the following techniques were applied:<br />

� The Federal Environmental Agency (“Umweltbundesamt“) conducts expert<br />

scientific monitoring in the field <strong>of</strong> waste management;<br />

� The Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors publishes an environmental report<br />

(“Umweltgutachten”) every two years by order <strong>of</strong> the German federal<br />

government. This report contains statements on questions <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management;<br />

� Further monitoring is performed by associations and research institutes (e.g.<br />

Gesellschaft für Verpackungsmarktforschung, GVM).<br />

17.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The following list <strong>of</strong> evaluation studies that have been undertaken prior to, and<br />

following the introduction <strong>of</strong>, the deposit refund system:<br />

29/09/09


343<br />

� Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen,<br />

SRU) Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2008, July 2008 (See:<br />

http://www.umweltrat.de for further information).<br />

� Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen,<br />

SRU) Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2004, July 2004 Council <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen, SRU)<br />

Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2002, July 2002.<br />

� Federal Environmental Agency (Umweltbundesamt, UBA), lifecycle assessment<br />

for beverage packaging II – body (Ökobilanz für Getränkeverpackungen II –<br />

Hauptteil), UBA-texts 37/00 (See http://www.umweltdaten.de/uba-infopresse/hintergrund/oebil.pdf)<br />

17.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The government’s ambitious target was to increase the market share <strong>of</strong> beverages<br />

sold in reusable drinks packaging and ecologically advantageous one-way drinks<br />

packaging to at least 80 per cent. Instead, the market share <strong>of</strong> reusable drinks<br />

packaging has continuously decreased.<br />

For a short period after the introduction <strong>of</strong> the one-way deposit policy the market<br />

share <strong>of</strong> beverages in returnable bottles increased in January 2003 to over 61 % from<br />

52.2 % at the end <strong>of</strong> 2002. The market share for multi-trip packaging for beer rose<br />

from 74.7% to 91%, for Coca Cola and for lemonade beverages, from 50.5% to 75.8<br />

%, and for water from, 67 to 78.7 %.<br />

But this was only a temporary rise as after 2004, the proportion <strong>of</strong> reusable<br />

packaging has been falling. For all drinks the market share <strong>of</strong> reusable packaging fell<br />

from 71.7% (1991) to 50.5% (2006). Table 17-1 shows the changes by type <strong>of</strong> drink,<br />

the summary translation <strong>of</strong> this information is given as follows:<br />

� Mineral waters, spring waters, table waters etc. exhibited a fall from 73% to<br />

52.6% between 2003 and 2006.<br />

� Carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks (specifically lemonades, including cola drinks, fizzy<br />

drinks) fell from 65.4% to 47.5%.<br />

� Non-carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks fell from 24% to 14%.<br />

� Only for beer (including alcohol-free beer and mixed drinks containing beer)<br />

did the quota remain more or less stable, with a small decrease from 89.2% to<br />

86.9%.<br />

According to the latest research conducted by GFK, the market share <strong>of</strong> reusable<br />

bottles for all alcohol-free drinks like water, s<strong>of</strong>t drinks or fruit-juice has dropped to<br />

27,2% in the first half-year 2008. This means an overall 25% lower share than before<br />

the deposit on drinking packages was introduced in 2003. 377 One-way PET-bottles,<br />

377 EUWID from 19.08.2008, p.6.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


with a market share <strong>of</strong> 63%, are the most favoured packaging type followed by<br />

reusable PET-bottles with 13.7% and glass-bottles with 13.5%. 378<br />

Table 17-1: Market Share <strong>of</strong> Reusable Packaging<br />

Overview Overview <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the the Quota Quota for for for Returnable Returnable Drinks Drinks Drinks Packaging Packaging (Mehrwegquote) (Mehrwegquote) from from 1991 1991 until until 2006 2006<br />

2006<br />

Year Year Year<br />

1991 1995 1995 2000 2000 2002 2002 2003 2003 2004 2004 2004 2005 2005 2006<br />

2006<br />

All All Beverages Beverages 71.7 71.7 72.3 72.3 72.3 65.0 65.0 56.2 56.2 63.6 63.6 60.3 60.3 60.3 56.0 56.0 50.5<br />

50.5<br />

Mineral<br />

Water<br />

Carbonated<br />

S<strong>of</strong>t Drinks<br />

344<br />

29/09/09<br />

93.3 89.0 81.0 68.3 73.0 67.6 60.9 52.6<br />

73.7 75.3 67.0 54.0 65.4 62.2 54.4 47.5<br />

Beer 82.2 79.1 72.8 68.0 89.2 87.8 88.5 86.9<br />

Noncarbonated<br />

S<strong>of</strong>t Drinks<br />

34.6 38.2 33.6 29.2 24.0 20.6 17.1 14.0<br />

Wine 28.6 30.4 25.0 25.3 24.6 20.0 19.0 17.5<br />

Source: GVM 1/2008<br />

Introduction <strong>of</strong> a deposit for Mineral<br />

water, s<strong>of</strong>t drinks and beer (without<br />

fruit-juices and nectars)<br />

A remarkable slowdown <strong>of</strong> sale-figures for cans, from 7.2 billion cans per year to just<br />

under 3 billion cans in 2004 was observed. 379 Discounters switched from selling<br />

alcohol-free drinks and beer in cans to glass-bottles (for beer) or PET-bottles (for<br />

alcohol-free drinks). The switch for sparkling drinks (like beer or s<strong>of</strong>t drinks) has gone<br />

hand in hand with new PET-technologies (nano-particular layers for PET-bottles) which<br />

prevent CO2 loss from the product.<br />

Comparing the market share <strong>of</strong> ecologically-unfriendly one-way drinking packaging<br />

with ecologically-friendly one-way and reusable containers shows a clear shift in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> the first group between 2004 to 2006. As Figure 17-1 shows, ecologicallyunfriendly<br />

one-way packaging (yellow) rose from 28.9% to 40.3%, ecologically-friendly<br />

one-way packaging (blue) remained at about 4.2% and reusable packaging (green)<br />

fell from 66.3% to 55.5%.<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> the one-way deposit for drinking bottles to reduce the littering <strong>of</strong> the<br />

landscape with drinking packages has been achieved, according to the Federal<br />

Environment Ministry. 380 Furthermore it can be observed, anecdotally, across the<br />

countryside that due to the refunds available, these products are either not thrown<br />

away, or are collected by people to receive the deposit. The compulsory deposit is a<br />

378 EUWID from 19.08.2008, p.6.<br />

379 EUWID from 14.02.2006, p. 2.<br />

380 EUWID from 19.08.2008, p. 6.


step towards turning people away from their “throw-away mentality”. The deposit on<br />

cans and one-way bottles has reduced the littering <strong>of</strong> streets, public places and<br />

landscapes with drinking bottles.<br />

Figure 17-1: Reusable vs. One-way Containers<br />

Source: German Environmental Agency (Umweltbundesamt) 2006, Texte 15/08<br />

Note: ecologically-unfriendly one-way packaging = yellow<br />

ecologically-friendly one-way packaging = blue<br />

reusable packaging = green<br />

17.6 Implementation Costs<br />

In 2006 discounters estimated that they will have to pay in total at least €1.315<br />

billion until 2010 for the take back-system for one-way-bottles (65 million Euro for<br />

administrative costs, 500 million Euro for simple reverse vending machines, 750<br />

million Euro for elaborated reverse vending machines). 381 However, these discounters<br />

sell one-way-bottles very pr<strong>of</strong>itably to the tune <strong>of</strong> about €400 million per annum. The<br />

cross-subsidisation they use comprises saved fees for the DSD, i.e. manufacturer and<br />

distributors <strong>of</strong> drinks packaging for which deposits have to be charged are exempted<br />

from the collection duties and fees under the Dual System for packaging (see Art. 9<br />

para 3 Packaging Ordinance), pr<strong>of</strong>it from selling the raw material <strong>of</strong> the PET-bottles<br />

and any unredeemed deposits. 382 A joint evaluation <strong>of</strong> the Federal Ministries <strong>of</strong><br />

Environment and Economics calculated that the deposit system costs less than one<br />

Euro cent per package, taking into account set up and operating costs.<br />

381 EUWID from 14.02.2006, p. 2.<br />

382 EUWID from 30.01.2007, p. 5.<br />

345<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


17.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Following the introduction <strong>of</strong> the one-way-deposit, one-way packaging materials were<br />

optimized, e.g. new manufacturing processes for cans and glass packaging, giving<br />

material savings <strong>of</strong> over 30% relative to 1991, when the Packaging Ordinance came<br />

into force.<br />

Following the introduction <strong>of</strong> the one-way deposit on drinking bottles, manufacturers<br />

<strong>of</strong>fered a variety <strong>of</strong> deposit-return machines, some machines taking all types and<br />

sizes <strong>of</strong> drinking packages from PET to glass.<br />

17.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The social implications <strong>of</strong> the policy do not obviously affect any one <strong>of</strong> group<br />

households in an adverse way compared to others. There is the potential for a limited<br />

regressive impact.<br />

Reusable containers were being squeezed out <strong>of</strong> the market before the mandatory<br />

deposit was introduced. However, after 1 st <strong>of</strong> January 2003, there was an upsurge in<br />

the market for re-usable packaging. In the first year after the introduction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

deposit, clear growth was recorded in the use <strong>of</strong> reusable packaging. Therefore the<br />

deposit played a role in maintaining employment in the reusable sector by stabilising<br />

reusable systems. Furthermore the deposit on cans is also creating jobs amongst<br />

manufacturers <strong>of</strong> deposit-return machines and in logistics enterprises.<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> economic implications, drinks sellers have had to cope with a number <strong>of</strong><br />

different types <strong>of</strong> packaging. Each chain responded differently to the deposit rules.<br />

The companies claimed that up to 25,000 people would loose their jobs in 2004 as a<br />

result <strong>of</strong> the deposit. This has been disputed by the Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Environment, which speaks <strong>of</strong> a job shift from large-scale production to medium-sized<br />

enterprises.<br />

On the other hand, contrary trends can be observed. In the sector for returnable<br />

packaging, major investments took place and new jobs were created. The German<br />

beer brewery “Krombacher”, for example, has invested 25 million Euros since the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the deposit policy. The one-way deposit has reportedly created<br />

14,400 new jobs in parts <strong>of</strong> the beverage economy, according to an unpublished<br />

study for the Federal Ministry for Economy and Labour in the first half <strong>of</strong> 2008.<br />

For the small and medium-size breweries in Bavaria, which only sell bottled beer, the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> the deposit on cans proved to be extremely positive. Double digit<br />

growth rates for small and medium-seized breweries were not unusual. After years <strong>of</strong><br />

declining market shares, the downward trend was reversed. 383<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the new deposit regulation has affected the whole beverages<br />

market. The impact on beverage sales was notable. Sales volumes have fallen in<br />

some sectors subject to the deposit, and increased in others.<br />

383 EUWID, No. 35 08/2003, p. 11.<br />

346<br />

29/09/09


The sectors that pr<strong>of</strong>ited from the Regulation consist both <strong>of</strong> types <strong>of</strong> beverages<br />

subject to, and those not subject to, the deposit fee. The increasing sector consists,<br />

for example <strong>of</strong> still s<strong>of</strong>t drinks, not subject to the deposit, but also <strong>of</strong> water, which is<br />

included in the deposit refund system. It is argued that this outcome could be<br />

explained partly by a shift in the behaviour <strong>of</strong> consumers from one kind <strong>of</strong> beverage to<br />

another one in order to avoid the payment <strong>of</strong> the deposit, for example from<br />

carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks bearing a deposit to non-carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks and juices<br />

which are not deposit-bearing. Beer and classic carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks on the other<br />

hand were sold less. Consumer Organisations claim that the drink producers avoid<br />

the one-way-deposit by declaring the used carbonic acid as a technical essential<br />

additive instead <strong>of</strong> an ingredient. Or they use sugar substitute instead <strong>of</strong> sugar. 384<br />

17.9 Complementary Policies<br />

Complementary Policies are the PAYT and the Packaging Ordinance introducing the<br />

Dual Systems (e.g. the DSD).<br />

17.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The system clearly has costs which need to be borne by the affected actors. These<br />

actors might, to a degree, <strong>of</strong>fset fees paid to the conventional packaging recovery<br />

systems.<br />

17.11 Lessons Learned<br />

The political and the public responses to the policy have been quite different.<br />

The beverage industry and the retail industry (especially the discounter markets Aldi,<br />

Lidl and Plus) resisted the planned introduction <strong>of</strong> the deposit on cans. But there was<br />

acceptance from the environmental federations and the reusable packaging industry.<br />

Also the German States (Länder) were divided into supporters and opponents, so that<br />

an extensive political debate was held between the federal government and the<br />

Upper House <strong>of</strong> the parliament (the representation <strong>of</strong> the Länder in the legislative<br />

procedure).<br />

The supporters <strong>of</strong> the deposits referred to the fact that during the utilization <strong>of</strong> oneway<br />

packages, there is a greater environmental impact. More resources continue to<br />

be used if one-way packaging is used instead <strong>of</strong> reusable packaging. The opponents<br />

<strong>of</strong> the deposit take the view that the recovery <strong>of</strong> one-way beverage packing is usually<br />

possible; very high recycling rates can be reached and thus can be seen as equivalent<br />

to re-usable packaging.<br />

The subject <strong>of</strong> the “Dosenpfand” was <strong>of</strong> great significance for the German public. The<br />

Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment commissioned a survey in June and October <strong>of</strong><br />

2003, questioning 2,000 citizens in order to understand their position on the<br />

mandatory deposit system. 75 % <strong>of</strong> the respondents stated that they are in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

the deposit duty. 48 % <strong>of</strong> the interviewees stated that they have had mostly good<br />

384 EUWID from 05.09.2006, p.8.<br />

347<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


experiences with the nationwide return system. Around 70 % however were not<br />

satisfied with the way in which the retail markets were applying the system.<br />

According to an inquiry by the Bielefelder market research institute on behalf <strong>of</strong> the<br />

working group packaging and environment, the new deposit regulation, which became<br />

effective on 1 st <strong>of</strong> October 2003, is a failure. The institute had asked 600 households<br />

via telephone between 2 nd and 6 th <strong>of</strong> October. According to the study 78 % <strong>of</strong> the<br />

German households are <strong>of</strong> the opinion that the new system <strong>of</strong> one-way packaging did<br />

not improve the situation in relation to the pre-existing system. 52 % pronounced that<br />

they were in favour <strong>of</strong> an abolishment <strong>of</strong> the deposit obligation. 26 % <strong>of</strong> respondents<br />

criticised some shops for refusing to take back packaging or to pay back the deposit.<br />

36% feel the return <strong>of</strong> empty cans and bottles is annoying. 28 % complained about<br />

delays at the till. 51% buy fewer or no cans, or one-way packages, because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

deposits. 385<br />

Over several years the German Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors<br />

(“Sachverständigenrat für Umweltfragen, SRU”) reached the conclusion that the<br />

deposit system for one-way containers should be withdrawn. The SRU regard the<br />

deposit as ecologically ineffective and economically inefficient. 386 Under the current<br />

legal climate, after the amendment <strong>of</strong> the packaging ordinance, the SRU sees further<br />

possibilities to encourage reusable systems to meet environmental and economic<br />

objectives. 387<br />

The facts show that in terms <strong>of</strong> prevention, the major impact has been a material<br />

switch from cans to (reusable) glass for beer. Also, probably facilitated by parallel<br />

technological change, there has been a change to PET bottles, which now account for<br />

76% <strong>of</strong> the drinks container market, which is split into 63% one-way and 13%<br />

reusable.<br />

The key success and failure factors <strong>of</strong> the policy for one-way deposits are:<br />

348<br />

� Standardised deposit regulation (no differentiation by content <strong>of</strong> beverage);<br />

� A standardised level <strong>of</strong> deposit (25 euro cents); and<br />

� A nationwide deposit-return system.<br />

No variation in the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Ordinance across Germany was identified.<br />

17.12 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

These are the essential elements that are required for this particular policy to be<br />

introduced:<br />

� Political willingness;<br />

385 EUWID, No. 43 from October 2003, p.8.<br />

386 Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (SRU), Environmental Report 2002 (“Umweltgutachten”), p. 411.<br />

387 SRU, Environmental Report 2004, p. 350.<br />

29/09/09


349<br />

� Willingness <strong>of</strong> the industry to take on responsibility for the system, e.g.<br />

organising the take-back system;<br />

� Ability to build up the requisite infrastructure, e.g. establishment <strong>of</strong> a collecting<br />

system;<br />

� Clarity in the legal regulations: It is important to regulate which kind <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging is subject to deposit;<br />

� As well as the introduction <strong>of</strong> the prerequisite statutory regulations, the<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> the logistics infrastructure is crucial for the implementation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

deposit on cans. This includes, in particular, the relevant infrastructure for<br />

implementing deposit-return systems (setting up <strong>of</strong> reverse vending machines,<br />

as well as transport and recovery operations).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


18.0 National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme -<br />

Ireland<br />

18.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The <strong>Policy</strong> Document ‘Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong> - Delivering Change (2002)’<br />

was published by the DoEHLG in March 2002. The document set out an agenda <strong>of</strong><br />

initiatives designed to achieve progress at the top <strong>of</strong> the waste hierarchy, in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

preventing waste arising in the first place and achieving improved levels <strong>of</strong> recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste that does arise. Funding to modernise recycling infrastructure in Ireland and<br />

other initiatives such as the introduction <strong>of</strong> a landfill levy (subsequently introduced in<br />

mid-2002) and new Producer Responsibility Initiatives were among the instruments<br />

envisaged in this policy document.<br />

To achieve the goals laid out in this document it was proposed to establish a Core<br />

Prevention Team within the EPA to implement a National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

Programme (NWPP). The objective <strong>of</strong> the NWPP was to establish a programme to<br />

deliver substantive results on waste prevention and minimisation across all waste<br />

streams. The goal is to stabilise waste risings, reverse current trends in waste<br />

production, decouple waste generation from economic growth and minimise the<br />

environmental impact <strong>of</strong> waste 388 .<br />

The Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government announced funding<br />

<strong>of</strong> €2 million to start a broad waste prevention initiative in April 2004. The<br />

Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) was invited to lead this programme and<br />

immediately published an Outline Work Plan 2004-2008. The EPA has published a<br />

new Prevention Plan 2009-2012, this document is presented as a framework<br />

statement <strong>of</strong> intent for work to be completed on the Prevention Programme for the<br />

four-year period to 2012, subject to resources being available.<br />

The NWPP has a number <strong>of</strong> initiatives / policies in place in order to prevent waste<br />

from being produced. The initiatives described in what follows are derived directly<br />

from the 2002 <strong>Policy</strong> Document.<br />

Green Green Schools<br />

Schools<br />

Green-Schools, known internationally as Eco-Schools, is an international<br />

environmental education programme, environmental management system and award<br />

scheme that promotes and acknowledges long-term, whole school action for the<br />

environment. Green-Schools covers a number <strong>of</strong> different themes, initially with litter<br />

and waste minimisation and followed by themes such as energy, water, transport, and<br />

healthy living. There are seven steps in this Programme, and all seven steps must be<br />

implemented in order to apply for an award.<br />

388 EPA (2004) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Outline Work Plan 2004 to 2008, Wexford:<br />

EPA, April 2004.<br />

350<br />

29/09/09


Green-Schools is run by An Taisce for over ten years, in co-operation with Local<br />

Authorities throughout Ireland and is sponsored by Coca-Cola Bottlers Ireland Ltd. and<br />

The Wrigley Company Ltd. along with leading integrated waste management company<br />

Greenstar. Green-Schools is an initiative <strong>of</strong> FEE - Foundation for Environmental<br />

Education and is referred to internationally as Eco-Schools.<br />

Over 2,880 primary, secondary and special schools in Ireland (~ 67% <strong>of</strong> all Irish<br />

schools) are currently taking part in the programme and 1,277 have been awarded<br />

the Green Flag. The Irish Green-Schools programme is one <strong>of</strong> the most successful<br />

within the international network and the key to this is partnership between the<br />

Schools, Environmental Education Unit <strong>of</strong> An Taisce and Local Authorities i.e. the<br />

financial and time contribution <strong>of</strong> the Local Authorities to the programme. Each <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Local Authorities (City & County Councils) has an Environmental Education Officer<br />

(EEO). These <strong>of</strong>ficers provide on the ground support to schools undertaking the<br />

programme.<br />

Green Green Home Home Programme<br />

Programme<br />

The pilot programme, which began in November 2006, is intended to promote waste<br />

prevention in the homes <strong>of</strong> the school children associated with Green Schools, thus<br />

targeting some <strong>of</strong> the wider community. To date ten community areas have been<br />

surveyed and six community focus meetings have been held. At these family-centred<br />

events, a range <strong>of</strong> environmental issues are presented in a practical manner<br />

focussing on solutions and behaviour change required for their implementation at<br />

home. Issues discussed include energy, water conservation, composting and waste.<br />

New material on waste prevention is currently being developed. A website at<br />

www.greenhome.ie is populated with relevant material to support the project. The<br />

Green Home programme was piloted in several areas and is being expanded in 2009<br />

to include up to 9,000 households.<br />

Green Green Green Business Business Initiative Initiative<br />

Initiative<br />

The Green Business Initiative is a project designed to promote waste prevention and<br />

resource efficiency within the business sector and amongst organisations generally.<br />

The Green Business Initiative works with enterprises and other organisations by<br />

providing practical tools and independent support to enable users to save money and<br />

increase pr<strong>of</strong>its, whilst helping the environment. There are three main projects<br />

currently underway within the Green Business Initiative:<br />

351<br />

� Hotels Hotels Sectoral Sectoral Projects Projects - the Green Hospitality Award is available to hotels<br />

and similar businesses that demonstrate progress towards environmental<br />

sustainable practices. 135 <strong>of</strong> Ireland’s largest hotels are already engaged in<br />

this project. Businesses can apply for assessments against bronze, silver, gold<br />

and platinum award criteria. Awards are granted depending on the businesses’<br />

achievements towards implementing environmental management systems<br />

and demonstrating real savings in water and energy consumption and waste<br />

generation.<br />

� Greenbusiness.ie Greenbusiness.ie – this web site contains information and tools to help<br />

businesses and other organisations save money and become more resource<br />

efficient. It includes waste and water audit tools, and provides a helpline for<br />

advice on best environmental practice. Linked to the website is a free site<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


352<br />

29/09/09<br />

advisory service whereby an experienced consultant will visit organisations for<br />

more tailored advice. By early 2009, more than 100 businesses had signed up<br />

to the website. 389<br />

� Case Case Case Study Study Study Implementation<br />

Implementation Implementation (CSI) – this includes finding examples <strong>of</strong> best<br />

practice in business and promoting these, by illustrating what cost and<br />

material savings are possible by adopting simple changes to business<br />

processes and practices.<br />

The Local Authority Prevention Demonstration (LAPD) (LAPD) Programme<br />

Programme<br />

There are 14 local authorities participating in the LAPD Programme, which was<br />

launched in July 2006. These local authorities have to date received €885,000 in<br />

grant aid to allow dedicated staff to work on local prevention projects. 390 The aim <strong>of</strong><br />

LAPD is to assist local authorities to design and implement local integrated waste<br />

prevention programmes and projects. In many instances, local authority staff have<br />

been specifically seconded to work on prevention projects. In total, 27 local authority<br />

staff have been directly involved in the projects. The idea is to develop capacity in<br />

local authorities such that their staff can in turn enable organisations, including their<br />

own, to prevent waste. 391<br />

18.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> policy in Ireland took a step forward in March 2002 with the publication <strong>of</strong> the<br />

policy document, “Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>: Delivering Change” which was<br />

specifically focused on waste prevention and recycling. This policy document sets out<br />

an agenda <strong>of</strong> initiatives designed to achieve progress at the top <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

hierarchy, in terms <strong>of</strong> preventing waste arising in the first place and achieving<br />

improved levels <strong>of</strong> recycling <strong>of</strong> waste that does arise.<br />

Accordingly, this <strong>Policy</strong> Statement:<br />

� Highlights the necessary disciplines that must be imposed within waste<br />

management systems to secure real progress on waste prevention, re-use and<br />

recovery; and<br />

� Recognises the need to reverse the trend <strong>of</strong> increasing waste generation and to<br />

decouple waste generation from economic growth.<br />

To achieve the above goals it was proposed to establish a Core Prevention Team<br />

within the EPA to implement the NWPP.<br />

389 EPA (2008) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Prevention Plan 2009 – 2012, Wexford: EPA.<br />

390 EPA (2008) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Prevention Plan 2009 – 2012, Wexford: EPA.<br />

391 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Fourth Annual Report 2007/08.


18.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

As discussed above, the NWPP and initiatives proceeded from the Preventing and<br />

Recycling <strong>Waste</strong> - Delivering Change (2002) document. The NWPP effectively started<br />

in 2004.<br />

18.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The following organisations each have a role to play in the NWPP:<br />

353<br />

� Environmental Protection Agency (EPA);<br />

� The Clean Technology Centre;<br />

� An Taisce;<br />

� Local Authorities; and<br />

� Businesses.<br />

18.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> prevention is difficult to appraise however the popularity <strong>of</strong> the NWPP<br />

programmes is a measure <strong>of</strong> their success.<br />

The EPA considers in the “NWPP Outline Work Plan 2004 to 2008” that indicators<br />

and targets for waste prevention are considered to be best developed in relation to<br />

projects initially and later to sectors as practical prevention experience is gained (e.g.<br />

in relation to hotels under Green Business Initiative).<br />

Green Green Schools Schools<br />

Schools<br />

In Ireland 67% <strong>of</strong> all Irish schools are currently taking part in the programme, with<br />

1,277 Schools have been awarded the Green Flag. This is a voluntary programme<br />

therefore schools consider this programme an important initiative, which they are<br />

willing to spend time and resources on this programme. The section below on<br />

“Evaluation Studies Available”, details some evaluations that have been completed by<br />

An Taisce in relation to the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the Green Schools Programme in waste<br />

prevention.<br />

Green Green Homes<br />

Homes<br />

Green Homes was set up in November 2006 with a total <strong>of</strong> seven schools<br />

participating (The pilot programme is intended to promote waste prevention in the<br />

homes <strong>of</strong> the school children associated with the original initiative thus targeting<br />

some <strong>of</strong> the wider community). In 2007, the number <strong>of</strong> schools increased to 18 and<br />

in 2008 this increased to 41 schools, which is nearly six times the number <strong>of</strong> schools<br />

participating in 2006. This illustrates the prominence <strong>of</strong> this programme. The Green<br />

Home Phase II Results, 2008 are outlined below under Evaluation Studies Available.<br />

There are currently no evaluation studies available for Phase III. The Green Home<br />

programme is being expanded in 2009 to include up to 9,000 households. The<br />

programme now revolves around the website with householders invited to register<br />

and be provided with information on waste prevention, water conservation and energy<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


use. A range <strong>of</strong> meetings with teachers, participating schools and feedback<br />

mechanisms are used to disseminate best prevention practice. 392<br />

Green Green Green Business Business<br />

Business<br />

The ‘Green Hospitality Awards’ project commenced in January 2008. By early 2009<br />

up to 200 hotels had signed up to this scheme and 80 had achieved their awards.<br />

Participants are provided with expert advice and assistance towards achieving waste<br />

prevention and water, energy and resource conservation. Awards (bronze, silver, gold<br />

and platinum) are formally made to recognise their achievements confirmed by<br />

audits. 393<br />

It is hoped to recruit 500 participants by the end <strong>of</strong> 2011. The fact that this is being<br />

extended to encompass other sectors including restaurants, pubs and contracting<br />

catering illustrates that it is a successful Programme.<br />

The The Local Local Authority Authority Prevention Prevention Demonstration Demonstration (LAPD) (LAPD) Programme<br />

Programme<br />

To date 14 local authorities are participating in the LAPD Programme, which was<br />

launched in July 2006. Overall over 153 businesses have been contacted and 96<br />

engaged with directly on prevention. Over 295 waste audits have been completed<br />

and 1,300 people attended over 20 different events organised to discuss the<br />

prevention projects.<br />

18.5.1 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The following studies are <strong>of</strong> relevance:<br />

354<br />

� A Research study completed in 2001 entitled “The Performance <strong>of</strong> the Irish<br />

Green-Schools Research Programme”<br />

� Green Schools Handbook, Towards a Sustainable Lifestyle, An Taisce.<br />

� An Taisce, Green Home Phase II Results, 2008 Presentation sent to TOBIN<br />

from Green Home Project Manager<br />

� EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Third Annual Report 2006/07<br />

and Fourth Annual Report 2007/08.<br />

18.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

� Green Schools: The aim <strong>of</strong> Green-Schools is to increase students’ and<br />

participant awareness <strong>of</strong> environmental issues through classroom studies and<br />

to transfer this knowledge into positive environmental action in the school and<br />

also in the wider community. Schools that have successfully completed all the<br />

elements <strong>of</strong> the programme are awarded the ‘Green-Flag’. This award has now<br />

become a well-recognised Eco-Label. The award has to be renewed every two<br />

years.<br />

392 EPA (2008) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Prevention Plan 2009 – 2012, Wexford: EPA.<br />

393 EPA (2008) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Prevention Plan 2009 – 2012, Wexford: EPA.<br />

29/09/09


355<br />

� Green Homes: The Green Homes Programme aims to promote waste<br />

prevention and sustainable living in the homes <strong>of</strong> the schools children<br />

associated with the An Taisce Green Schools initiative as well as targeting the<br />

wider community.<br />

� Green Businesses: The aim <strong>of</strong> the Green Business initiative is to deliver<br />

substantive results and savings on resource efficiency; through waste<br />

prevention and minimisation and reduction in energy and water consumption.<br />

� LAPD: The LAPD Programme assists local authorities to design and implement<br />

local integrated waste prevention programmes and projects. This allows local<br />

authority staff to enable organisations including their own, to prevent waste<br />

from being produced.<br />

18.6.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

Green Green Green Schools Schools<br />

Schools<br />

A Research study completed in 2001 entitled “The Performance <strong>of</strong> the Irish Green-<br />

Schools Research Programme”; the primary aim <strong>of</strong> this work was to quantify any<br />

reduction in waste to landfill achieved by the programme. The approach taken to the<br />

project was to undertake a comparative study <strong>of</strong> the schools undertaking the<br />

programme; these schools included Pre-Action Plan Schools, Post-Action Plan Schools<br />

and Awarded Green Schools (who have implemented the Seven Steps <strong>of</strong> the Green<br />

Schools Programme). The results are outlined in Table 18-1. The results indicate that<br />

a considerable waste to landfill reduction occurs during a school’s progress through<br />

the programme. This study revealed that schools that had been awarded the Green<br />

Flag were diverting on average <strong>of</strong> 45% more <strong>of</strong> their waste away from landfill in<br />

comparison to schools that were not participating in the programme. Several <strong>of</strong> the<br />

awarded schools were very close to achieving zero waste to landfill, with some<br />

producing as little as 2 grams <strong>of</strong> waste per person per day. 394<br />

This study illustrates that the Green Schools Programme is an important mechanism<br />

for preventing waste arisings.<br />

Table 18-1: Average <strong>Waste</strong> to Landfill Per Capita Values for the Three School Groups<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Pre-Action Plan Post-Action Plan Awarded<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> per capita per day 53.2g 37.9g 29.0g<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> the Green Schools Programme, schools monitor the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

produced; this results in both less waste being disposed <strong>of</strong> to landfill and less waste<br />

being produced in the first instance (waste prevention). This study revealed that<br />

monitoring was being undertaken by a number <strong>of</strong> methods. These included<br />

monitoring by weight, by volume, counting the number <strong>of</strong> bags or bins going to the<br />

landfill. From this study it was apparent that schools that monitored their waste<br />

394 Green Schools Handbook, Towards a Sustainable Lifestyle, An Taisce.


typically generated less waste to landfill or produced less waste (waste prevention) in<br />

the first instance.<br />

This study also revealed that the average per capita values for Primary Schools is<br />

38.55g/person/day while for secondary school it is 55.1g/person/day.<br />

Further research carried out in 2006 indicated that the awarded schools had<br />

improved their performance and on average were diverting just over 60% <strong>of</strong> their<br />

waste from landfill. Out <strong>of</strong> sample <strong>of</strong> 160 schools, over 8% (13 schools) were diverting<br />

in excess <strong>of</strong> 90% <strong>of</strong> their waste from landfill. Calculations indicate that around 5<br />

tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste is directly diverted from landfills per school day in Ireland due to the<br />

work <strong>of</strong> Green-Schools. 395<br />

Green Schools promotes environmental awareness in 67% <strong>of</strong> all Irish Schools 396, this<br />

leads to the following outcomes in terms <strong>of</strong> waste prevention:<br />

356<br />

� Behaviour towards the environment was significantly different. Students from<br />

awarded Green-Schools drop less litter, take part in more local environmental<br />

projects, conserve more water and more electricity, and are more conscious <strong>of</strong><br />

the environment when making a purchase than their non-Green-Schools<br />

counterparts;<br />

� Green-Schools students are better “opinion leaders” for the environment, i.e.<br />

they discuss the environment with more people and in more settings,<br />

particularly the classroom, and provide more encouragement to their peers<br />

than their non-Green-Schools counterparts; and<br />

� The main environmental concern indicated by both types <strong>of</strong> student was litter.<br />

Green Green Homes<br />

Homes<br />

Green Home Phase II Results illustrate that this programme has encouraged<br />

communities to prevent waste from being produced. Figure 18-1 below illustrates that<br />

in 2008, 42% <strong>of</strong> those Communities involved in the Green Homes Pilot Programmes<br />

avoid buying over packaged goods; this is an increase from 34% in 2007.<br />

395 Ibid.<br />

396 An Taisce, Green Home Phase II Results, 2008 Presentation sent to TOBIN from Green Home<br />

Project Manager.<br />

29/09/09


Figure 18-1: Green Homes Research – Packaging <strong>Waste</strong><br />

50%<br />

45%<br />

40%<br />

35%<br />

30%<br />

25%<br />

20%<br />

15%<br />

10%<br />

5%<br />

0%<br />

357<br />

34%<br />

42%<br />

We avoid buying over-packaged goods<br />

46%<br />

44%<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

6%<br />

2%<br />

8% 7%<br />

Always Sometimes Not Sure Never<br />

"07 Pre Green Home<br />

"08 Post Green Home<br />

Source: Presentation by An Taisce Green Home Phase II Results, 2008<br />

In addition the survey results illustrate that there was a 5% increase in people<br />

composting their waste; a 7% increase in the recycling <strong>of</strong> plastic bottles and a 7%<br />

increase in people recycling paper. 397<br />

Phase III <strong>of</strong> the Green Home programme commenced in September 2008 and will<br />

involve 40 newly recruited schools and up to 9,000 more families. Community links<br />

will be widened to include the Tidy Towns Network, National Spring Clean, Green<br />

Coast and LAPD/N participants. Online membership in September 2008 was 290<br />

members, this has increased to 2,200 in February 2009. 398 The programme has a<br />

strong emphasis on action based activity where participants undertake household<br />

challenges around the themes <strong>of</strong> waste, energy, water and transport, the aim <strong>of</strong> which<br />

is to support householders as they reduce their household utility bills and also help to<br />

protect the environment. The growth <strong>of</strong> the programme since its inception in 2006<br />

suggests that this programme has been successful to date.<br />

Green Green Business<br />

Business<br />

A major Green Business Initiative the Green Hospitality Awards scheme, which has<br />

been developed, based on previous work completed by EPA/ERTDI on the Cleaner<br />

Greener Production Programme project “Greening Irish Hotels”. The original<br />

programme involved 56 hotels (3 to 5 star) ranging in size from 30 to 255 beds<br />

located around the country. Environmental reviews, training, environmental<br />

management, best practices and cleaner production plans were developed.<br />

397 An Taisce, Green Home Phase II Results, 2008 Presentation sent to TOBIN from Green Home<br />

Project Manager.<br />

398 Dorothy Stewart, Green Homes Project Manager, An Taisce.


Quantified actual savings included diversion <strong>of</strong> 1,113 tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste from landfill,<br />

reduction <strong>of</strong> 5,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> water consumption and 3,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> carbon<br />

emissions. If extrapolated across the entire sector the economic benefit could<br />

amount to €81.4 million in cost savings, and diversion <strong>of</strong> 56,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

from landfill. 399<br />

This project is currently being developed further with up to 200 hotels being actively<br />

recruited throughout the country by early 2009. A range <strong>of</strong> awards and assessment<br />

criteria have been developed to underpin this project.<br />

It is anticipated that considerable quantities <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste can be<br />

prevented or diverted from landfill with the continued implementation <strong>of</strong> the Greening<br />

Irish Hotels project under the Green Business Initiative (up to 70% biodegradable 400).<br />

By reducing packaging, preventing waste, increasing re-cycling and segregation the<br />

hotels have saved 4,000 tonnes (1,600 full skips) <strong>of</strong> landfill waste. This is equal to<br />

monetary savings <strong>of</strong> between €5,000 and €45,000 per hotel. Eight per cent <strong>of</strong> Irish<br />

Hotels are now accredited to the scheme. The target for 2009 is to expand the<br />

current membership <strong>of</strong> 180 hotels and catering firms to 300. It is also intended to<br />

expand the scheme to other similar sectors, including contract catering, nursing<br />

homes and hospitals, which should also realise significant diversion <strong>of</strong> biodegradable<br />

waste. 401 The level <strong>of</strong> waste reported in the National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, allied with<br />

the need for businesses to reduce costs in 2009, reflects the need for continued<br />

support for this Scheme. The fact that this Scheme is being extended to encompass<br />

other sectors including restaurants, pubs and contracting catering demonstrates the<br />

success <strong>of</strong> this Programme.<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> the Green Business website (www.greenbusiness.ie ) a <strong>Waste</strong> Audit Tool<br />

(WAT) was developed, which allows business to break down the types, volumes and<br />

sources <strong>of</strong> waste, helping business to monitor, prevent waste from being produced<br />

and hence reduce costs. Using this WAT many businesses in Ireland have already<br />

started making resource efficiency savings by reducing the amount <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

produced, water consumed and energy used. Hotels, manufacturers and food<br />

processors have shown to successfully reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> waste being disposed <strong>of</strong><br />

in landfill site without in any way compromising the quality <strong>of</strong> service or levels <strong>of</strong><br />

comfort <strong>of</strong>fered by the hotel to its customers.<br />

LAPD LAPD<br />

LAPD<br />

As mentioned above the LAPD Programme assists local authorities to design and<br />

implement local integrated waste prevention programmes and projects. This allows<br />

local authority staff to enable organisations including their own, to prevent waste from<br />

being produced. Example projects include Dundrum Shopping Centre which has<br />

reduced waste charges by approximately €168,000 annually following a waste audit<br />

and the introduction <strong>of</strong> improved practices. They are currently testing an on site<br />

399 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Fourth Annual Report 2007/08.<br />

400 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Third Annual Report 2006/07.<br />

401 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Fourth Annual Report 2007/08.<br />

358<br />

29/09/09


composter. There are similar savings in Hospitals in Monaghan where improving<br />

waste management practices and avoiding mixing hazardous with non hazardous<br />

waste reduced waste charges by €8,300.<br />

18.6.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

While the main focus <strong>of</strong> the above mentioned schemes is waste prevention, recycling<br />

is also promoted for example:<br />

359<br />

� Green Schools: In Green Schools recycling levels <strong>of</strong> glass, paper, cardboards<br />

and aluminium, as well as the levels <strong>of</strong> home composting were significantly<br />

higher within the homes <strong>of</strong> Green School students.<br />

� Green Homes: Green Homes participants are encouraged to reduce their<br />

waste output through reducing the amount <strong>of</strong> purchased goods which are<br />

excessively packaged, and through composting and recycling.<br />

� Green Business: WAT under Green Business identifies the amount <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

recycled and its annual waste cost, thus encouraging recycling for businesses.<br />

� LAPD: While the main aim <strong>of</strong> the LAPD programme is waste prevention,<br />

recycling is also promoted for example in Phase I Programmes Limerick County<br />

Council reviewed waste <strong>Management</strong> in conjunction with SISK Building<br />

Contractors. Targets were set to reduce the total number <strong>of</strong> mixed skips at the<br />

development, through waste prevention practices and the recycling was<br />

encouraged through the introduction <strong>of</strong> segregated skips. Under Phase II,<br />

which relates to Projects, Dundrum Town Centre segregating food waste and<br />

they are currently trailing an on-site composter.<br />

All <strong>of</strong> the above programmes are being expanded, continually promoted, encouraged<br />

and funded; this suggests that these programmes have been successful in waste<br />

prevention and recycling. However the current schemes need to be extended<br />

considerably in order to fully see the impact on the national waste arising figures.<br />

18.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government announced funding<br />

<strong>of</strong> €2 million to start a broad waste prevention initiative in April 2004 from the<br />

Environmental Fund. In 2007/8, the EPA provided 50% <strong>of</strong> the external costs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

packaging prevention programme operated by Repak. The source <strong>of</strong> funding for<br />

subsequent phases <strong>of</strong> the programme is the subject <strong>of</strong> ongoing review. 402<br />

The Environmental Fund Account, 2006 stated that in 2006, €1,644,063 was given<br />

to the NWPP. To that point, the EPA stated that almost €5 million from the<br />

Environment Fund has been expended or committed to these projects, 403 whilst<br />

according to the Environmental Fund Account, 2007, another €1,484, 300 was<br />

committed to the NWPP in 2007.<br />

402 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Prevention Plan 2009 – 2012, Wexford: EPA.<br />

403 National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Third Annual Report, 2006- 2007.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


As part <strong>of</strong> the NWPP, an agreement to co-fund a Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

Programme has been signed by NWPP and Repak. A budget <strong>of</strong> €200,000 for 2007<br />

has been approved.<br />

There is no detail <strong>of</strong> how much each Programme costs.<br />

Householder and Business do not pay to register for either Green Homes or Green<br />

Schools. However, it seems reasonable to suggest that the programme is not costless<br />

to engage with, if only due to demands on staff time. That does not, <strong>of</strong> course, mean<br />

that these costs are recouped through lessons learned whilst engaging with the<br />

programme.<br />

18.8 Response from Public and Industry<br />

Response to the Green Schools, Green Homes and Green Business Initiatives has<br />

been positive from both the public and Industry. Industry is responsive to the Green<br />

Business Initiatives, especially the Hotel Sector as the savings from diversion <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

from landfill, reduction in water consumption & carbon emissions if extrapolated<br />

across the entire sector the economic benefit could amount to €81.4 million in cost<br />

savings. It is apparent that the public are responsive to these initiatives as the Green<br />

Schools is now being rolled out to communities in the form <strong>of</strong> Green Homes.<br />

18.9 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The Green Schools Programme has expanded to include the Green Homes<br />

Programme; this is to promote environmental awareness in communities also.<br />

18.10 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

There are no obvious adverse consequences associated with any <strong>of</strong> these initiatives.<br />

It is possible that some companies may be less able, or feel less able, to commit time<br />

to the programme.<br />

18.11 Complementary Policies<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> prevention measures, and the desire to engage with them, will be<br />

strengthened where the costs <strong>of</strong> waste management are higher. Hence, there are<br />

overlaps with the landfill levy, and pay-by-use policies.<br />

18.12 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

These initiatives do not change the prices <strong>of</strong> resources and services. They do,<br />

however, address market failures in respect <strong>of</strong> waste prevention activity, notably<br />

information failures, and the transaction costs experienced by companies, schools<br />

and homes seeking to understand the opportunities to save money through cost<br />

effective waste prevention measures.<br />

All <strong>of</strong> the above programmes developed as part <strong>of</strong> the NWPP are a resource for<br />

school, householders and business in minimising cost to their business. Businesses<br />

can access for free, www.greenbusiness.ie and review all <strong>of</strong> the Case Studies by<br />

business on cost savings from waste prevention initiatives etc... Schools can access<br />

www.greenschoolsireland.org and review case studies, research undertaken and<br />

360<br />

29/09/09


information on the various themes including “litter and waste”. Communities /<br />

householders can access www.greenhome.ie and review case studies.<br />

These websites have the relevant information to allow businesses, schools and<br />

householder to prevent waste from being produced and reduce fuel bills by learning<br />

from best practice case studies and implementing these actions into their<br />

lifestyle/business.<br />

18.13 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The above three Programmes are Voluntary Initiatives which were as a direct results<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong> - Delivering Change (2002) policy statement.<br />

Therefore, there are no evasion or enforcement issues.<br />

18.14 Lessons Learned<br />

18.14.1 General Lessons<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the obvious lessons learned is that measures which seek to provide<br />

information regarding waste prevention and recycling can lead to improved<br />

performance in both respects. The question which logically follows is ‘how can<br />

companies, schools and homes, or any one or more <strong>of</strong> these groups, be persuaded to<br />

adopt such measures in a more systematic fashion? In other words, can these<br />

‘initiatives’ be made less voluntaristic through fashioning a relevant policy? Such a<br />

policy would, it seems, have the potential to deliver savings to business and society<br />

more generally.<br />

361<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


19.0 Producer Responsibility, WEEE - Ireland<br />

19.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The Directive on waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE Directive) was<br />

founded on the principle <strong>of</strong> "Producer Responsibility" and its general objectives are:<br />

362<br />

� To prevent waste <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic equipment (EEE) and to promote<br />

the reuse, recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> such wastes;<br />

� To improve the environmental performance <strong>of</strong> all operators involved in the life<br />

cycle <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic equipment, e.g. producers, distributors and<br />

consumers and in particular those operators directly involved in the treatment<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste electrical and electronic equipment.<br />

The WEEE Regulations transpose the WEEE Directive into Irish law; the WEEE<br />

Regulations came into effect on 13 August 2005.<br />

The WEEE Directive applies across ten categories <strong>of</strong> EEE. The following 10 categories<br />

have been identified in the WEEE Directive as belonging to EEE:<br />

� Large household appliances<br />

� Small household appliances<br />

� IT and telecommunications equipment<br />

� Consumer equipment<br />

� Lighting equipment<br />

� Electrical and electronic tools<br />

� Toys, leisure and sports equipment<br />

� Medical devices<br />

� Monitoring and control instruments<br />

� Automatic dispensers<br />

The WEEE Directive requires producers to be responsible for the financing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

collection, treatment, recovery and environmentally sound disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE from 13<br />

August 2005. This means that final users <strong>of</strong> such household WEEE are entitled to<br />

return their WEEE free <strong>of</strong> charge, either to retail outlets in instances where a<br />

replacement item is purchased, or to other authorised collection points, including<br />

local authority civic amenity sites.<br />

29/09/09


Producers must register with the national registration body, the WEEE Register<br />

Society, and report to the Black Box 404 the amount in units and weights (kg) <strong>of</strong> EEE<br />

and/or batteries or accumulators placed onto the Irish market on a monthly basis.<br />

At present, there are two approved compliance schemes in Ireland: the European<br />

Recycling Platform (ERP) and WEEE-Ireland. If a producer <strong>of</strong> Electrical and Electronic<br />

Equipment (EEE) is not a member <strong>of</strong> an approved compliance scheme they are<br />

required to self-comply in accordance with the WEEE Regulations. Self-compliance is<br />

particularly relevant to producers who primarily sell Business to Business (B2B).<br />

WEEE fees in Ireland are calculated as follows:<br />

363<br />

� Companies placing EEE onto the market up until 31st December 2006 will be<br />

charged a registration fee <strong>of</strong> €600 and a 2005/2006 annual fee <strong>of</strong> €600.<br />

� 2007 and 2008 annual fees will be charged based on EEE turnover (turnover<br />

> €250,000 = €600, turnover < €250,000 = €400) and a discount allowed (-<br />

€300) for Producers signing up to direct debit payment.<br />

� Producers not placing EEE onto the market prior to 31st December 2006 will<br />

be charged a €600 registration fee plus the relevant annual fee.<br />

� Once they are fully registered with the scheme, Producers will be invoiced for<br />

all Environmental <strong>Management</strong> Costs (EMCs) owed to date based on the Black<br />

Box reporting.<br />

� For Producers <strong>of</strong> Automotive Batteries there is a €600 Registration fee and an<br />

annual fee <strong>of</strong> €300 (to be paid by direct debit).<br />

� For Producers <strong>of</strong> Portable Batteries and Accumulators there is a €600<br />

Registration fee and annual fees based on Battery turnover (Turnover ><br />

€250,000 = €600, Turnover < €250,000 = €400) with a €300 discount for<br />

Producers signing up to direct debit<br />

� Existing members <strong>of</strong> WEEE Ireland received free membership for Portable<br />

battery compliance until 31st December 2008.<br />

From 13 August 2005, each retailer must:<br />

� Be registered with their local authority;<br />

� Provide free in-store take back <strong>of</strong> household WEEE on a one-for-one basis on<br />

the sale <strong>of</strong> a new replacement product;<br />

� Ensure that any WEEE collected is delivered to an approved collection facility;<br />

� Ensure that the storage and transport <strong>of</strong> WEEE collected as above meets the<br />

requirements <strong>of</strong> the Regulations; and<br />

404 WEEE Register Society Ltd have appointed Deloitte to manage and operate the WEEE Blackbox<br />

function on its behalf. The information gathered will be used to establish producers’ financial liabilities<br />

associated with the management <strong>of</strong> a proportion <strong>of</strong> the WEEE arising in Ireland.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


364<br />

� Ensure that private households are informed <strong>of</strong> the WEEE take back facilities<br />

available to them and that they are encouraged to participate in the separate<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE.<br />

Since 13 August 2005, each local authority must accept household WEEE free <strong>of</strong><br />

charge at its civic amenity facilities. Local authorities can no longer charge gate fees<br />

for WEEE. Where appropriate, priority should be given to reuse <strong>of</strong> the whole<br />

appliance, thereby contributing to waste prevention.<br />

19.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

Many everyday consumer items are classified as electrical and electronic equipment<br />

such as mobile phones, computers, drills, hairdryers, as well as industrial equipment,<br />

medical devices and laboratory equipment. When these items reach their end-<strong>of</strong>-life<br />

they are defined as WEEE. WEEE is made up <strong>of</strong> many different materials and<br />

components, some <strong>of</strong> which are hazardous. The increased consumption <strong>of</strong> electrical<br />

and electronic equipment, together with a decrease in the average lifespan <strong>of</strong><br />

products has resulted in a waste stream that is growing three times faster than the<br />

average waste stream. This growth, together with the presence <strong>of</strong> several hazardous<br />

substances in many products, has lead to the development <strong>of</strong> European legislation on<br />

WEEE. Today, citizens are likely to generate between 17 and 20kg <strong>of</strong> WEEE per<br />

inhabitant per annum<br />

Producers are required to meet various recovery, recycling and reuse targets for<br />

WEEE, calculated based on the weight <strong>of</strong> equipment collected. 405 There are different<br />

targets for the recovery and recycling <strong>of</strong> the different categories. For large household<br />

appliances, which include fridges and freezers, the rate <strong>of</strong> recovery must be at least<br />

80% with component material and substance reuse and recycling a minimum <strong>of</strong> 75%<br />

by average weight by appliance. For televisions and monitors, the rate <strong>of</strong> recovery<br />

must be at least 75% and component material and substance reuse and recycling a<br />

minimum <strong>of</strong> 65% by average weight by appliance. Similar targets apply for other<br />

WEEE items. These targets must be achieved by 31 st December 2008.<br />

Retailers are also responsible for the collection, treatment, and environmentally<br />

sound disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE. Thus final users are entitled to return their WEEE free <strong>of</strong><br />

charge to retail outlets when a replacement item is also purchased.<br />

The WEEE Directive emerged, and has evolved in the following ways:<br />

• 2005: The EU WEEE Directive 2002/96/EC was transposed into Irish law in<br />

August 2005 by the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (<strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic<br />

Equipment) Regulations 2005.<br />

405 'Producer' means any person who, irrespective <strong>of</strong> the selling technique used, including by means <strong>of</strong><br />

distance communication, manufactures and sells electrical and electronic equipment under his or her<br />

own brand, resells electrical and electronic equipment produced by other suppliers under his or her<br />

own brand, imports/exports electrical and electronic equipment on a pr<strong>of</strong>essional basis into/from the<br />

State or distributes electrical and electronic equipment from a producer who is deemed not to be<br />

registered under the provisions <strong>of</strong> article 12(2).<br />

29/09/09


365<br />

• 2008: The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (<strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment)<br />

(Amendment) Regulations 2008 were introduced in September 2008, which<br />

amend the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (<strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment)<br />

Regulations 2005.<br />

• 2008: The European Commission proposed amendments to the WEEE and<br />

Restriction on Hazardous Substances (RoHS) Directives in December 2008.<br />

The proposed directives set higher but more flexible targets on the collection<br />

and recycling <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic equipment and introduce greater<br />

coherence with other EU legislation. The main change they propose is to<br />

change the collection target from the current 4kg per capita per year to a<br />

variable target that takes into account the economies <strong>of</strong> individual member<br />

states. The new target is set at 65% <strong>of</strong> the average weight <strong>of</strong> products placed<br />

on the market in the two preceding years. Although many Member States have<br />

already reached this target it becomes binding in 2016, thus giving other<br />

Member States time to adjust. Ireland however has already exceeded these<br />

recovery targets, with the exception <strong>of</strong> the category ‘large household<br />

appliances.’ 406 The amendment also proposes the re-use <strong>of</strong> whole appliances<br />

as part <strong>of</strong> the existing re-use/recycling target. This will allow flexibility to<br />

choose the most sustainable treatment option (re-use or recycling) and will<br />

avoid making re-use an unattractive option by needing to meet higher recycling<br />

targets, even when re-use might be more economically and socially valuable.<br />

As about 5% <strong>of</strong> collected waste electrical and electronic equipment is suitable<br />

for reuse, the overall recovery targets have been increased by 5%. 407<br />

19.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The WEEE Regulations were introduced in August 2005 and amended in September<br />

2008.<br />

19.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

As well as consumers, there are a number <strong>of</strong> organisations involved in the<br />

implementation and management <strong>of</strong> this <strong>Policy</strong>. These include:<br />

� Producers:<br />

• Finance the take back <strong>of</strong> WEEE based on market share;<br />

• Register with the WEEE Register Society;<br />

• Self-comply or join an approved compliance scheme;<br />

• Mark products with crossed-out wheelie bin symbol.<br />

406 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Report, 2007.<br />

407 Press Release, 3 December 2008, ‘Environment: Commission proposes revised laws on recycling<br />

and use <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances in electrical and electronic equipment’, Europa.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


366<br />

� Retailers:<br />

29/09/09<br />

• Register premises with local authority;<br />

• Display environmental management costs <strong>of</strong> specified EEE;<br />

• Comply with requirements regarding price display and statutory notices;<br />

• Take back household WEEE free <strong>of</strong> charge when replacing on a one-forone,<br />

like for like basis;<br />

• Store, transport, and dispose <strong>of</strong> WEEE as set out in Regulations.<br />

� Local authorities:<br />

• Local enforcement responsibilities (particularly in relation to retailer<br />

obligations);<br />

• <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> civic amenity sites.<br />

� Environmental Protection Agency:<br />

• Leads national enforcement <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Regulations;<br />

• Promotion <strong>of</strong> eco-design and re-use <strong>of</strong> EEE.<br />

� WEEE Register Society Ltd. National producer registration body:<br />

• Registration <strong>of</strong> producers <strong>of</strong> EEE;<br />

• Notify Environmental Protection Agency where evidence <strong>of</strong> noncompliance;<br />

• Determine which categories/sub-categories EEE product belongs to;<br />

• Verification <strong>of</strong> visible environmental management costs;<br />

• Determination <strong>of</strong> market share <strong>of</strong> individual producers (function<br />

devolved to the “Black box” currently managed by Deloitte & Touche).<br />

� European Recycling Platform (ERP) – Ireland:<br />

• Approved producer compliance scheme.<br />

• Established in 2005 as a result <strong>of</strong> the success and expansion <strong>of</strong> ERP in<br />

Europe. ERP Ireland has 75 members and continues to grow annually.<br />

• To date ERP have collected 29,731 tonnes <strong>of</strong> recyclable waste from its<br />

members and the public.<br />

• ERP operate in Cavan, Clare, Fingal, Louth, Limerick, Meath, Monaghan<br />

and Kerry.<br />

� WEEE Ireland: 408<br />

408 WEEE Ireland is a not for pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation, founded by producers <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic<br />

appliances in order to comply with the legal obligations imposed by the WEEE Directive 2002/96/EC.


367<br />

• Approved producer compliance scheme.<br />

� <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage and Local Government:<br />

• Issues/amends the WEEE Regulations;<br />

• Provides guidance on the WEEE Regulations;<br />

• Represents Ireland at European Commission meetings (Technical<br />

Adaptation Committee).<br />

� Recovery Operators:<br />

• Possess relevant permits/ licences/ Certificates <strong>of</strong> Registration where<br />

necessary;<br />

• Storage and/or treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE as required under Sixth and<br />

Seventh Schedules <strong>of</strong> WEEE Regulations;<br />

• Recovery and recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE in line with 2008 recovery targets;<br />

• Recording and maintaining accurate records for WEEE.<br />

19.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

Since the WEEE Regulations came into force on 13th August 2005, EPA inspectors<br />

and contractors have been undertaking random, unannounced inspections <strong>of</strong><br />

retailers <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic equipment (EEE). 409 Significant efforts are being<br />

made also to identify any unregistered, potentially obligated producers or “freeriders”.<br />

Producers/distributors who supply EEE by means <strong>of</strong> distance communication<br />

(web-sites, mail order catalogues, telesales etc.) are also covered under the WEEE<br />

Regulations, and inspections <strong>of</strong> such operations are ongoing. All complaints received,<br />

from whatever source, are acted on as part <strong>of</strong> the surveillance effort.<br />

The following programme <strong>of</strong> inspection has been and continues to be undertaken:<br />

� Retailers: Retailers: Inspectors have now completed three campaigns <strong>of</strong> nationwide<br />

retailer inspections on the EPA’s behalf. These campaigns were carried out in<br />

May-June 2006, November- February 2007 and February-March 2008. EPA<br />

inspectors also carry out routine/non-routine inspections where necessary. To<br />

date, approximately 700 impromptu retailer inspections have been completed;<br />

� Distance Distance sellers: sellers: Inspections <strong>of</strong> distance sellers (web-sites, mail order<br />

catalogues) were made a priority due to concerns <strong>of</strong> non-compliance in this<br />

sector. A second round <strong>of</strong> distance seller inspections was completed in<br />

October 2007. Approximately 170 such inspections have been completed to<br />

date and non-compliances followed up with the relevant companies;<br />

WEEE Ireland can organise for the treatment and recycling <strong>of</strong> waste electrical and electronic<br />

equipment and batteries and accumulators from authorised collection points, on behalf <strong>of</strong> its Producer<br />

members.<br />

409 EPA (2007) EPA Enforcement <strong>of</strong> WEEE Regulations, http://www.epa.ie<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


368<br />

� Producers: Producers: Producers: The EPA is carrying out inspections <strong>of</strong> producers where it has been<br />

notified that they are non-compliant by the WEEE Register Society for failing to<br />

re-register. These are detailed inspections where purchase and sales<br />

documentation and stock held on site is inspected to gather evidence <strong>of</strong> noncompliance<br />

with obligations under the WEEE Regulations. Where noncompliance<br />

is not closed out within agreed time-frame, a recommendation for<br />

prosecution may be put to the Board <strong>of</strong> the Agency for consideration;<br />

� Trade Trade exhibitions: exhibitions: exhibitions: Inspectors attend exhibitions (open to public and/or trade)<br />

to check compliance <strong>of</strong> exhibitors selling or advertising EEE. The EPA is<br />

working with exhibition management companies to have terms and conditions<br />

regarding WEEE compliance inserted into exhibition application forms, and to<br />

ensure that non-compliant exhibitors are prohibited from attending future<br />

exhibitions.<br />

In summary the EPA collects and transfers data on the following aspects <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

management:<br />

� Amounts <strong>of</strong> products introduced to the market;<br />

� Annually recovered appliances; and<br />

� Volume <strong>of</strong> collected, reused, recovered and exported appliances.<br />

19.5.1 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

According to the WEEE Regulations, by 31 December 2006 Ireland was obliged to<br />

achieve a separate collection rate <strong>of</strong> 4kg <strong>of</strong> household WEEE per person per year.<br />

According to the:<br />

• National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2006, Ireland achieved a separate collection rate <strong>of</strong><br />

7.4Kg <strong>of</strong> household WEEE per person per year.<br />

• Annual WEEE Ireland Report 2007, this collection rate increased again in<br />

2007 to almost 9Kg. Of the total WEEE collected in 2007, 80% was treated in<br />

Ireland and 20% was exported to other EU countries. 410<br />

19.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

The WEEE Regulations aim to prevent the generation <strong>of</strong> WEEE and facilitate the<br />

achievement <strong>of</strong> targets for the collection, treatment, recovery and disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE in<br />

an environmentally sound manner. The quantity <strong>of</strong> WEEE collected in 2007 reached<br />

50,626 tonnes. 411 The EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Database Report 2006 stated that this<br />

producer responsibility initiative ‘has proven very successful in achieving the<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> waste electrical and electronic equipment and diverting it from landfill’.<br />

However, the report went on to suggest that the increasing generation <strong>of</strong> any waste<br />

stream is <strong>of</strong> concern and that as a next step, the focus should be firstly on preventing<br />

410 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Report, 2007.<br />

411 IBID.<br />

29/09/09


the generation <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic waste in the first place and secondly on<br />

promoting its reuse. 412 In December 2008 a proposal for revised laws on WEEE was<br />

drafted by the European Commission and one <strong>of</strong> the main adjustments the<br />

Commission proposes is to set a combined recycling and re-use target. This combined<br />

target would avoid making re-use an unattractive option by needing to meet higher<br />

recycling targets, hence would increase the environmental and social benefits<br />

associated with re-use.<br />

The WEEE Regulations aims to reduce quantities <strong>of</strong> WEEE disposed <strong>of</strong> via landfill and<br />

reduce the harmful effects caused by WEEE on health and the environment whilst<br />

conserving natural resources.<br />

19.6.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

As regards waste prevention, the main aim <strong>of</strong> the WEEE policy is to provide the<br />

following key environmental benefits:<br />

369<br />

� Reduce the waste produced whilst manufacturing WEEE products as well as<br />

the minimisation <strong>of</strong> waste produced at the end <strong>of</strong> the product’s life, both <strong>of</strong><br />

which lead to a reduction in WEEE being disposed <strong>of</strong> to landfill. However no<br />

statistics are currently available in Ireland on if the manufacturing rates <strong>of</strong><br />

WEEE.<br />

� Reduce the potential leakage <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials by controlling the toxicity<br />

<strong>of</strong> the product and ensuring its safe disposal (includes RoHS). Since July 2006<br />

new EEE cannot, other than the permitted trace levels, contain lead, mercury,<br />

cadmium, hexavalent chromium, polybrominated biphenyls (PBB) and<br />

polybrominated diphenyl ethers (PBDE);<br />

� Re-use <strong>of</strong> old electrical and electronic equipment. In a press statement in<br />

September 2007, the Minister said that: “There is vibrant social economy<br />

activity in refurbishing old electrical and electronic goods’, adding that ‘there<br />

is evidence that perfectly working equipment is being recycled instead <strong>of</strong><br />

being diverted for re-use.” The Minister mentioned that his <strong>Department</strong> is<br />

working with the relevant stakeholders, including the social economy sector in<br />

developing a protocol to promote and facilitate higher levels <strong>of</strong> reuse. This<br />

Protocol was to be completed by the end <strong>of</strong> 2007. 413 However, there was no<br />

information available on this protocol at the time <strong>of</strong> writing. 414 Re-use <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

requires fewer resources and less energy when compared with recycling or the<br />

manufacture <strong>of</strong> new products from virgin materials.<br />

412 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Report, 2006,<br />

http://www.epa.ie/downloads/pubs/waste/stats/name,24094,en.html<br />

413 Press Release “Recycling Rate for <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment Continues to Grow”,<br />

28/09/07.<br />

414 We understand from DoEHLG that the protocol is due to be published shortly (as <strong>of</strong> July 2009).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


19.6.2 Environmental Benefits - Associated with Recycling<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> management infrastructure for WEEE in Ireland is developing rapidly. There are<br />

now six facilities in Ireland that recover WEEE by dismantling it into the material<br />

components and processing it into reusable raw materials. As mentioned in Section<br />

19.5.1, in 2007 WEEE Ireland collected almost 9kg per person <strong>of</strong> electronic waste<br />

which greatly exceeded the 2008 target <strong>of</strong> 4kg per inhabitant set for Ireland by the<br />

EU. However, the current level may be somewhat below what is now proposed by the<br />

European Commission.<br />

Household WEEE taken back to retailers or deposited at civic amenity sites is<br />

collected for processing by one <strong>of</strong> WEEE Ireland’s contracted partners. The five<br />

families <strong>of</strong> WEEE are treated differently; the dedicated treatment processes ensure<br />

maximum recycling rates can be achieved for the various materials contained in<br />

WEEE.<br />

As shown in Table 19-1 considerable quantities <strong>of</strong> WEEE are recycled in Ireland. The<br />

EPA considers that producers and their compliance schemes should strive to ensure<br />

that this remains the case. 415<br />

Table 19-1: Recycling Rates <strong>of</strong> WEEE Families 2007<br />

EU Target 31 st<br />

Dec 2008<br />

WEEE Ireland<br />

Recovery Rate<br />

Recovered &<br />

Recycled<br />

370<br />

29/09/09<br />

Tonnes<br />

Fridge<br />

Freezers<br />

LHA<br />

Mixed<br />

WEEE<br />

CRT Lamps<br />

80.00% 80.00% 70.00% 75.00% n/a<br />

86.73% 68.23% 81.07% 96.71% 93.10%<br />

Ferrous Metal 14,302 66.66% 60.95% 42.43% 4.02% 0.00%<br />

Non Ferrous<br />

Metal<br />

2,146 4.53% 5.16% 11.55% 13.05% 3.10%<br />

Plastic 3,302 15.08% 2.12% 27.07% 15.60% 0.00%<br />

Glass 2,990 0.46% 0.00% 0.02% 64.04% 90.00%<br />

Total 22,740 86.73% 68.23% 81.07% 96.71% 93.10%<br />

Treatments &<br />

Landfill<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> 5,909 11.69% 31.75% 18.85% 3.28% 6.00%<br />

Hazardous <strong>Waste</strong> 95 1.58% 0.02% 0.08% 0.01% 0.90%<br />

Total 6,004 13.27% 31.77% 18.93% 3.29% 6.90%<br />

Source: WEEE Ireland, Annual Report 2007<br />

415 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Report, 2007.


80% <strong>of</strong> WEEE primary processing takes place in Ireland in permitted, and where<br />

appropriate, licensed facilities, with the reminder going to dedicated WEEE treatment<br />

facilities in the UK and mainland Europe. The processing <strong>of</strong> WEEE in this way means<br />

consumers can be confident their old and broken electrical appliances are managed<br />

by WEEE Ireland in an environmentally responsible way within Ireland. 416 Recycling<br />

WEEE saves energy, reduces raw material use and combats climate change.<br />

19.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The overall cost for compliance with the WEEE Directive is estimated at €500-900<br />

million per year EU-wide. Of this, €300-600 million will be spent on collection and<br />

€200-300 million on recovery, reuse and recycling.<br />

The WEEE Task Force Report on implementation <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Directive estimated that<br />

the cost <strong>of</strong> collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE would be in the region <strong>of</strong> €10 to €14m<br />

annually in Ireland. 417<br />

Producers have to fund the recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE arising from goods they place on the<br />

market after 13 August 2005, and also share in the cost <strong>of</strong> recycling WEEE arising<br />

from all goods placed on the market prior to this date. Producers must fund the<br />

management <strong>of</strong> this ‘historic waste’ on the basis <strong>of</strong> their current market share. The<br />

WEEE Directive requires that Member States ensure that for a transitional period <strong>of</strong><br />

eight years (10 years for large household appliances) producers are allowed to<br />

display the costs associated with the recycling <strong>of</strong> historic WEEE on the price <strong>of</strong> new<br />

products.<br />

The Visible Environmental <strong>Management</strong> Costs (vEMCs) that the producers are able to<br />

apply to new EEE in order to help pay for historic WEEE are based on the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling as approved by the WEEE Register Society Limited. These costs fund the two<br />

collective compliance schemes operating in Ireland, WEEE Ireland and the European<br />

Recycling Platform, to enable them to pay for the environmentally sound management<br />

<strong>of</strong> all household WEEE that is taken back by retailers or deposited by members <strong>of</strong> the<br />

public at local authority civic amenity sites.<br />

The vEMCs displayed to consumers cannot exceed the actual costs <strong>of</strong> recycling. The<br />

WEEE Register, the national registration body for producers, has verified and issued a<br />

schedule <strong>of</strong> vEMCs to be displayed. Example <strong>of</strong> EMCs which must be displayed for<br />

various products are as follows; large refrigerators and freezers - €30, large<br />

appliances such as washing machines, dryers, stoves and hobs, €5 and large<br />

television sets €8.<br />

416 WEEE Ireland (2007) The National Compliance Scheme for Electrical Recycling Annual Report<br />

2007.<br />

417 The WEEE Task Force Group is comprises representatives <strong>of</strong> all the key stakeholders. This Task<br />

Force plays a pivotal role in monitoring the continued implementation <strong>of</strong> the WEEE and RoHS<br />

Directives and in advising the <strong>Department</strong> and the Minister <strong>of</strong> further improvements and refinements<br />

to the WEEE regime in Ireland.<br />

371<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Additional costs to businesses may be incurred due to logistical efforts for the take<br />

back system; however the potential magnitude <strong>of</strong> these additional costs not clear.<br />

19.8 Response from Public and Industry<br />

The compliance schemes WEEE Ireland and ERP Ireland organise ‘Public Collection<br />

Days’ or ‘Open Days’ to encourage members <strong>of</strong> the public to bring their household<br />

WEEE free <strong>of</strong> charge to locations around the country as part <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Awareness-<br />

Raising Programme. These Open Days have had an exceptional response:<br />

approximately 250 tonnes <strong>of</strong> WEEE were collected over the period <strong>of</strong> the fifteen Open<br />

Days which were held by ERP. The most successful Open Day was held in Tralee, Co.<br />

Kerry, where 53 tonnes were collected in one day. Through the take back <strong>of</strong> old<br />

electronic and electrical equipment to retailers and civic amenity sites, half a million<br />

household appliances have been taken out <strong>of</strong> the waste stream and recycled since<br />

13 August 2005, including 85,000 fridge freezers, 78,000 TVs and almost 40,000<br />

power tools. 418 These figures suggest that householders are responding to the<br />

available channels for WEEE re-use / recovery.<br />

19.9 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The policy generates continuous incentives for improvement in product design, as<br />

well as promoting investment in infrastructure. Six companies have set up WEEE<br />

facilities in Ireland including Cedar Resource <strong>Management</strong>, Techrec and KMK Metals<br />

Recycling which process the majority <strong>of</strong> material collected from retailers, civic amenity<br />

sites, and distribution hubs. They handle all categories <strong>of</strong> WEEE providing it is<br />

available in suitable quantities. In addition Irish Lamp Recycling and Enva Ireland<br />

collect and recycle florescent tubes and gas discharge lamps nationwide.<br />

19.10 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

WEEE fees do not have direct distributional consequences. Indirectly however<br />

increased WEEE collection rates may lead to benefits in terms <strong>of</strong> social inclusion in<br />

two ways. First, there is the potential for an increase in the reuse <strong>of</strong> WEEE. This could<br />

result in second-hand EEE being made available to lower income groups. In addition,<br />

there may be additional opportunities for charities or voluntary organisations to<br />

provide training using second-hand EEE, for example for the long-term unemployed.<br />

One programme which encourages the reuse <strong>of</strong> WEEE is the Micros<strong>of</strong>t Authorised<br />

Refurbisher (MAR) programme which is designed to increase the number <strong>of</strong> low-cost<br />

computers available to charities and schools, whilst also keeping serviceable<br />

computers out <strong>of</strong> landfills. The company is also actively recruiting new refurbishing<br />

companies to join the programme so that increased volumes <strong>of</strong> computers can be<br />

refurbished for the benefit <strong>of</strong> as many non-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisations and schools as<br />

possible. There are currently four companies in Ireland actively refurbishing<br />

computers as part <strong>of</strong> the MAR programme and over 1,000 computers have been<br />

418 Press Release (6 December 2005) Electrical Equipment Take Back Scheme Proves Overwhelming<br />

Success, Leo Donovan, CEO, WEEE Ireland.<br />

372<br />

29/09/09


outed to charities and schools to date. Rehab Recycle is associated with the<br />

Micros<strong>of</strong>t MAR programme. Rehab Recycle provide a high quality IT reuse, refurbish<br />

and recycle service to customers and are one <strong>of</strong> the country's largest employers <strong>of</strong><br />

people with disabilities. The programme has also received the commendation <strong>of</strong><br />

WEEE Ireland; to date WEEE Ireland has financed over 200 <strong>of</strong> these refurbished<br />

computers in their 'schools awareness campaign' that is operated by Rehab. 419<br />

Secondly, increased separate collection may lead to less fly-tipping <strong>of</strong> WEEE, which<br />

would result in improvements in terms <strong>of</strong> visual disamenity, particularly in areas that<br />

have experienced disproportionate levels <strong>of</strong> flytipping in the past. In addition,<br />

separate collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE may have benefits in terms <strong>of</strong> increased awareness <strong>of</strong><br />

waste in general.<br />

19.11 Complementary Policies<br />

To tackle the growth in generation <strong>of</strong> WEEE, Ireland introduced the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Restriction <strong>of</strong> Certain Hazardous Substances in Electrical and<br />

Electronic Equipment) Regulations 2005, which were amended by the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Restriction <strong>of</strong> Certain Hazardous Substances in Electrical and<br />

Electronic Equipment) Regulations 2008. The RoHS Regulations requires that new<br />

electrical and electronic equipment being put on the market after 1 July 06 cannot,<br />

other than the permitted trace level, contain lead, mercury, cadmium, hexavalent<br />

chromium, polybrominated biphenyls (PBB) and polybrominated diphenyl ethers<br />

(PBDE) in electrical and electronic equipment, where alternatives are available. The<br />

main aim <strong>of</strong> the RoHS Regulations is to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> the six prescribed<br />

substances in the processing and recycling phases in the lifecycle <strong>of</strong> electrical and<br />

electronic equipment.<br />

In addition the Irish government implemented the Batteries Directive 2006/66/EC in<br />

September 2008. This Directive applies to all types <strong>of</strong> batteries and accumulators,<br />

regardless <strong>of</strong> their shape, volume, weight, material composition or use, including<br />

those incorporated into electrical and electronic equipment (EEE) and vehicles. Since<br />

26 September 2008, all Producers and Distributors (Retailers) <strong>of</strong> batteries must<br />

comply with these Battery Regulations. Producers <strong>of</strong> batteries must register with the<br />

WEEE Register Society and where they are supplying portable or automotive batteries<br />

can join a compliance scheme such as WEEE Ireland to help meet their collection,<br />

recycling and reporting requirements as specified in the Regulations.<br />

19.12 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

As mentioned in “Implementation Costs”, a visible Environmental <strong>Management</strong> Cost<br />

(vEMC) to fund the cost <strong>of</strong> the environmentally sound management <strong>of</strong> historic WEEE,<br />

has been added to the cost <strong>of</strong> new EEE products. The vEMC’s are assigned for<br />

recycling activity and are not diverted elsewhere. The system should lead to an<br />

improvement in the efficiency with which resources are use, though it seems likely<br />

419 Micros<strong>of</strong>t Ireland (2008) Micros<strong>of</strong>t's PC Re-use Programme Encourages Low-Cost PCs for Schools<br />

and Charities, http://www.micros<strong>of</strong>t.com/ireland<br />

373<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


that the effect on prices might not reflect either the full costs <strong>of</strong> collection, or the<br />

environmental costs <strong>of</strong> materials use.<br />

19.13 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

In 2006 the WEEE Monitoring Group was established. Representatives from all the<br />

key stakeholders are involved and play a pivotal role in monitoring the continued<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the WEEE and RoHS Directives and in advising the <strong>Department</strong><br />

and the Minister <strong>of</strong> further improvements and refinements to the WEEE regime in<br />

Ireland.<br />

The EPA is working closely with the WEEE Register Society (the national producer<br />

registration body) on producer enforcement, particularly those who fail to register,<br />

who fail to join a compliance scheme or self-comply, or who fail to report what they<br />

place on the market to the WEEE Blackbox.<br />

The EPA is also continuing to follow up on any complaints regarding “free-riders”, i.e.<br />

unregistered producers who are continuing to place EEE on the market. Unregistered<br />

producers fail to contribute their share to the cost <strong>of</strong> environmentally sound<br />

management <strong>of</strong> WEEE. Where specific instances <strong>of</strong> transgression have been<br />

identified, Notifications <strong>of</strong> Non-Compliance are issued. Where the EPA receives no<br />

response or the company continues in non-compliance, a Final Warning Letter may<br />

issue to the company. Inspections are scheduled where non-compliances persist, and<br />

may be followed by legal action where the company fails to comply. The EPA calls<br />

compliance meetings with producers/retailers where necessary in order to raise<br />

awareness <strong>of</strong> non-compliance with senior management and agree corrective actions<br />

going forward. The EPA refers non-compliant print advertising to the Advertising<br />

Standards Authority for Ireland (ASAI) for follow through with their media member<br />

organisations. The Broadcasting Complaints Commission (BCC) processes complaints<br />

relating to noncompliant television and radio advertising.<br />

The EPA and the National Consumer Agency (NCA) also work together to ensure<br />

correct pricing <strong>of</strong> EEE at retail premises. NCA inspectors visited over 200 premises in<br />

late 2005 to check that the retail price <strong>of</strong> EEE products on the shelf were in<br />

compliance with the Product Prices Regulations. Any complaints regarding price<br />

splitting are forwarded to the NCA for their information and follow up.<br />

The EPA is hopeful that those contacted will work towards compliance without<br />

recourse to legal action. However to date, the EPA has taken prosecutions against a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> different retailers and producers for failure to comply with producer<br />

obligations under the WEEE Regulations. The companies were all convicted in the<br />

District Court and fines and costs were awarded to the EPA.<br />

Under the WEEE Regulations, local authorities have responsibility for enforcement <strong>of</strong><br />

retailer obligations. A Producer Responsibility Enforcement Network has been in place<br />

374<br />

29/09/09


since June 2006 to guide and co-ordinate local authorities in their enforcement <strong>of</strong><br />

producer responsibility initiatives. 420<br />

The EPA is currently carrying out inspections for RoHS compliance. The initial focus is<br />

on high-risk items, i.e. those associated with a high probability <strong>of</strong> non-compliance<br />

and/or those with a high probability <strong>of</strong> being disposed <strong>of</strong> in the general household<br />

waste stream. The EPA is contributing to European Environment Agency (EEA)-wide<br />

enforcement activities through the EU RoHS Enforcement Bodies Network.<br />

There have been self-reported non-compliances, which were discovered by the<br />

producers at very early stages. Some <strong>of</strong> the infringements required remedial actions<br />

which have already been carried out.<br />

19.14 Lessons Learned<br />

Through this policy:<br />

375<br />

� Industry is encouraged to design its products for the purpose <strong>of</strong> reuse and<br />

recyclability;<br />

� Collection and treatment infrastructure is tailored to the amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

disposed.<br />

� Consumers find the take back comfortable and are not illegally disposing <strong>of</strong><br />

their small electric appliances in the residual waste. However, there is no<br />

evidence available that fly-tipping <strong>of</strong> WEEE is decreasing as a consequence <strong>of</strong><br />

this Directive.<br />

The degree to which the re-use / prevention aspects <strong>of</strong> the policy have been actively<br />

pursued / enforced have probably been somewhat limited, but the proposed re-use<br />

protocol (due for publication shortly) may improve matters in respect <strong>of</strong> re-use.<br />

420 EPA (2008) ‘Note on Enforcement <strong>of</strong> the WEEE and Battery Regulations by the EPA’<br />

www.epa.ie/downloads/pubs/waste/weee/epa_enforcement<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


20.0 Producer Responsibility, WEEE -<br />

<strong>International</strong><br />

20.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong> electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) is currently one <strong>of</strong> the fastestgrowing<br />

waste streams, increasing at a rate three times that <strong>of</strong> average municipal<br />

waste growth. 421 In the EU, the WEEE directive (2002/96/EC) has been implemented<br />

with the purpose <strong>of</strong>, as a first priority, the prevention <strong>of</strong> WEEE, and in addition the reuse,<br />

recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> WEEE, thereby reducing the need for its disposal. By<br />

applying a ‘cradle to grave’ approach to EEE products, it also seeks to improve the<br />

environmental performance <strong>of</strong> all operators involved in the life cycle <strong>of</strong> electrical and<br />

electronic equipment, in particular those operators directly involved in the treatment<br />

<strong>of</strong> WEEE. As a companion to the WEEE Directive, Directive 2002/95/EC on the<br />

Restriction <strong>of</strong> Hazardous Substances (RoHS) also aims to minimise the use <strong>of</strong> certain<br />

hazardous materials in newly-produced EEE, both to increase the pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling WEEE, and to minimise the release <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances into the<br />

environment by controlling the disposal route <strong>of</strong> older EEE at the end <strong>of</strong> its life.<br />

Producers <strong>of</strong> EEE must provide evidence that the concentrations <strong>of</strong> hazardous<br />

materials are below defined levels. The six key restricted substances are lead,<br />

cadmium, mercury, hexavalent chromium, polybrominated biphenyls and<br />

polybrominated diphenyl.<br />

The EU WEEE regulations apply to the categories <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic<br />

equipment listed below, with sub-categories being the business-to-consumer (B2C)<br />

stream (which ends up pre-dominantly in the householder waste stream) and the<br />

business-to-business (B2B) stream:<br />

376<br />

� Category 1 - Large household appliances;<br />

� Category 2 - Small household appliances;<br />

� Category 3 - IT & telecoms equipment;<br />

� Category 4 - Consumer equipment;<br />

� Category 5 - Lighting equipment;<br />

� Category 6 - Electrical & electronic tools;<br />

� Category 7 - Toys, leisure & sports equipment;<br />

� Category 8 - Medical devices;<br />

� Category 9 - Monitoring & control equipment; and<br />

421 CIWM (2008) Are You WEEE Aware?, The Chartered Institution <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>s <strong>Management</strong>, September<br />

2008 Issue, pp. 31-32.<br />

29/09/09


377<br />

� Category 10 - Automatic dispensers.<br />

WEEE regulations must be complied with for all those who generate, handle or<br />

dispose <strong>of</strong> waste that falls under one <strong>of</strong> these categories. The WEEE Directive is quite<br />

precise with regard to producer responsibility, specifically referring to “producers”,<br />

providing a definition <strong>of</strong> what constitutes a “producer” and requiring them to<br />

undertake specific actions. Until recently, these actions were as follows: 422<br />

5) producers must take into account waste management at the design stage <strong>of</strong> the<br />

product e.g. by making design modifications that make WEEE easier to dismantle,<br />

recycle and recover;<br />

6) producers must guarantee fixed re-use and/or recycling and recovery rates either<br />

individually or via collective organisations (the WEEE directive currently sets a<br />

minimum collection target <strong>of</strong> 4 kg per annum per inhabitant for WEEE from<br />

households);<br />

7) producers are obliged to finance at least the collection, treatment, recovery and<br />

environmentally-sound disposal <strong>of</strong> household WEEE deposited at collection sites;<br />

and<br />

8) for WEEE placed on the market after 13th August 2005, producers are obliged to<br />

finance those operations associated with the waste from their own products/<br />

production processes.<br />

Distributors are also linked to the WEEE producer responsibility via an obligation to<br />

take back products free <strong>of</strong> charge on a ‘one-for-one’ or ‘old-for-new’ basis.<br />

In December 2008, however, a proposal for revised laws on WEEE has been drafted<br />

by the European Commission. With regard to bullet point 2 above, it is proposed that<br />

the collection target be altered from 4 kg per annum per inhabitant to a 65 %<br />

collection rate, calculated according to the average amount <strong>of</strong> EEE placed on the<br />

market in the two preceding years. In addition, in order to encourage the re-use <strong>of</strong><br />

whole appliances, it is proposed that such re-use be included within the 65 % target.<br />

The proposal also goes further than bullet point 3, suggesting that Member States<br />

should, where appropriate, encourage producers to finance all the cost related to<br />

collection facilities for B2C WEEE.<br />

Several countries outside the EU, including Japan, South Korea, Canada, Norway and<br />

Switzerland, have also implemented some form <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility with regard<br />

to WEEE. Their policies generally look similar in that they attempt to encourage firstly<br />

the re-use, and secondly, the recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE. These countries also combine their<br />

WEEE policy with a policy similar to the RoHS, to try to prevent hazardous material<br />

from WEEE being released into the environment. However, the list <strong>of</strong> EEE to which the<br />

policy applies, and the way in which the safe collection and disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE are<br />

funded, varies slightly in some <strong>of</strong> these countries. Such variations are discussed<br />

further in Section 20.2.<br />

422 ACR+ (2007) Extended Producer Responsibility, Introducing the Debate…, Journal for Sustainable<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, Warmer Bulletin 112, pp 3-4.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


20.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

In the EU, the WEEE directive (2002/96/EC) became European law in February 2003,<br />

with all MS except Malta and the UK having transposed at least framework<br />

regulations associated with the directive by 13 th August 2005.<br />

Similar regulations surrounding WEEE are also in place in Norway and Switzerland. In<br />

March 1998, Norway signed an agreement concerning the “Reduction, Collection and<br />

Recovery <strong>of</strong> Electric and Electronic Appliances” with producers, importers and<br />

retailers all being made responsible for the take back <strong>of</strong> appliances. In Switzerland, a<br />

collection and recovery system for fridges has been in place since 1991, linked to the<br />

requirement to remove and safely dispose <strong>of</strong> CFCs from these appliances. The<br />

Ordinance on the Return, the Take-Back and the Disposal <strong>of</strong> Electrical and Electronic<br />

Appliances subsequently came into force in Switzerland in 1998.<br />

Outside <strong>of</strong> Europe, comparable policies on responsibility for WEEE have also been<br />

placed on the producer. In April 2001, the Electrical Household Appliance Recycling<br />

Law (EHARL) took effect in Japan with responsibility for refrigerators, washing<br />

machines, air conditioners and televisions shifted from local governments to<br />

producers. 423 Likewise, China also has its own WEEE regulations, with Administration<br />

Order No. 40 - the <strong>Management</strong> Measures for the Control <strong>of</strong> Environmental Pollution<br />

by Electronic <strong>Waste</strong> - setting out disassembly, utilization and disposal criteria for all<br />

types <strong>of</strong> EEE. In 2007, South Korea also implemented legislation for WEEE entitled<br />

the ‘Act for Resource Recycling <strong>of</strong> Electrical/Electronic Products and Automobiles’.<br />

Various provinces within the USA and Canada are also currently implementing their<br />

own version <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Directive, designating a list <strong>of</strong> categories <strong>of</strong> EEE that require<br />

waste-diversion programmes. In 2004, California introduced an Electronic <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Recycling Fee on all new monitors and televisions to cover the cost <strong>of</strong> their recycling;<br />

in 2007 Ontario introduced a similar fee for computers and accessories, monitors,<br />

printers, fax machines and televisions, and is also looking to add PDAs, copiers,<br />

flatbed scanners, phones and audio-visual equipment to this list in the near future. 424<br />

Reasons for the implementation <strong>of</strong> WEEE policies in these countries are discussed in<br />

further detail in Section 20.5, with most driven primarily by legal requirement linked<br />

to environmental benefit. Further details on how WEEE policy has been implemented<br />

in specific countries is presented in Section 20.2.1.<br />

20.2.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

Table 20-1 summarises some <strong>of</strong> the key elements <strong>of</strong> WEEE policy implementation<br />

within the EU, focusing on the registration <strong>of</strong> producers, reporting requirements,<br />

responsible parties and financial obligations. Two key reviews used to produce this<br />

423 M. Yamaguchi (2002) Extended Producer Responsibility in Japan – Introduction <strong>of</strong> “EPR” into<br />

Japanese <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> and some Controversy, Japanese Environmental <strong>Management</strong> Association for<br />

Industry, ECP Newsletter 19, 1-12.<br />

424 S. Deffree (2008) Ontario Begins WEEE Directive Compliance, Electronic Design, Strategy, News,<br />

[Accessed 8 th October 2008], http://www.edn.com/index.asp?layout=article&articleid=CA6535361.<br />

378<br />

29/09/09


table are the ‘2008 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Directive 2002/96 on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic<br />

Equipment (WEEE)’ produced by the United Nations University (2007) 425 and ‘The<br />

Producer Responsibility Principle <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Directive’ presented by Ökopol<br />

(2007). 426 Additional references are provided throughout the document.<br />

Supplementary details for several countries listed in Table 20-1, as well as for non<br />

EU-based examples, are also given in this section. In addition, a more detailed case<br />

study for Germany is given in Section 21.0.<br />

Key points to be drawn from Table 20-1 are as follows:<br />

379<br />

� According to the WEEE Directive, all MS require that their producers and<br />

distributors <strong>of</strong> EEE be registered. For those MS for which information is<br />

available, Germany, Denmark, Finland, Hungary, Ireland, Poland, Portugal and<br />

the United Kingdom all charge their producers and distributors <strong>of</strong> EEE for<br />

joining the national register. In addition, Denmark, Ireland, Poland and<br />

Portugal also require that their producers and distributors re-new this<br />

registration annually;<br />

� Reporting requirements vary from bi-monthly to annually, with most requiring<br />

at least the ten category split, and a split by B2B/B2C (with the definition <strong>of</strong><br />

this split varying from country to country); the implications <strong>of</strong> the variations in<br />

reporting requirements are discussed in more detail in Section 20.4;<br />

� The responsibilities associated with the set-up and running <strong>of</strong> the initial<br />

household collection infrastructure for WEEE (i.e. the physical responsibilities)<br />

were not specified in the Directive. Bulgaria, Cyprus, Latvia and Sweden<br />

subsequently assign this responsibility solely to the producer, whereas<br />

Denmark and Germany assign such responsibility to the municipality and<br />

Poland assign it to the distributor. The remaining countries use some<br />

combination <strong>of</strong> these three key parties;<br />

425 United Nations University (2007) 2008 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Directive 2002/96 on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and<br />

Electronic Equipment (WEEE), Final Report produced for the European Commission.<br />

426 Ökopol (2007) The Producer Responsibility Principle <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Directive, Report produced for the<br />

European Commission.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 20-1: Summary <strong>of</strong> WEEE policies in EU countries<br />

National National Register<br />

Register<br />

for for for Producers<br />

Producers<br />

Reporting Reporting Requirements Requirements for<br />

for<br />

Producers<br />

Producers<br />

Responsibility Responsibility for for Household Household WEEE<br />

WEEE<br />

Physical Physical Responsibility<br />

Responsibility<br />

Financial Financial Responsibility Responsibility (ex (extended) (ex tended) (Infrastructure (Infrastructure set set-up). set up).<br />

a<br />

Producer Producer<br />

Producer<br />

Responsibility Responsibility for for<br />

for<br />

Non Non-Household<br />

Non Household<br />

WEEE<br />

WEEE<br />

Country<br />

Country<br />

Annual<br />

Annual Frequency<br />

Frequency<br />

Joining<br />

Joining<br />

Renewal<br />

Renewal <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Fee<br />

Fee<br />

Required<br />

Required Reporting<br />

Reporting<br />

Deviations<br />

Deviations<br />

from<br />

from<br />

Reporting<br />

Reporting<br />

Under Under<br />

Under<br />

Categories<br />

Categories<br />

1-10 10<br />

B2B/<br />

B2B/<br />

B2C<br />

B2C Distributor Distributor Municipality Municipality Producer Producer Distributor Distributor Distributor Municipality Municipality Producer<br />

Producer<br />

split<br />

split<br />

Financing<br />

Financing<br />

Structure<br />

Structure<br />

for for for hh<br />

hh<br />

WEEE WEEEb<br />

Historica Historicalc New<br />

New<br />

380<br />

AT Free Yes<br />

BE - -<br />

BG - -<br />

29/09/09<br />

Quarterly/<br />

Annually<br />

Monthly/<br />

Quarterly<br />

Monthly/<br />

Quarterly<br />

5 categories Yes � � � � � - R1 Producer<br />

Also subcategories<br />

Yes � � � S1 R1 Producer<br />

- Yes � � S2 R1 Producer<br />

CY - - - - - � � S1 R1 Producer<br />

CZ Free No Annually None Yes � � � � S1 R1 Producer<br />

DE Yes No Monthly<br />

B2C/<br />

Annually<br />

DK Yes Yes Annually<br />

- - � � S2 R2 Producer<br />

Also subcategories<br />

Yes � � S2 R1 Producer<br />

EE Free No Annually None No � � � � S1 R1 Producer<br />

ES Free No Quarterly<br />

Also subcategories<br />

FI Yes No Annually None Yes<br />

Yes � � � - R1 Producer<br />

�<br />

�<br />

�<br />

S2 R1 Producer


National National Register<br />

Register<br />

for for Producers<br />

Producers<br />

Reporting Reporting Requirements Requirements for<br />

for<br />

Producers<br />

Producers<br />

Responsibility Responsibility for for Household Household WEEE<br />

WEEE<br />

Physical Physical Responsibility<br />

Responsibility<br />

Financial Financial Responsibility Responsibility (ex (extended) (ex tended) (Infrastructure (Infrastructure set set-up). set set up).<br />

a<br />

Producer<br />

Producer<br />

Responsibility Responsibility for<br />

for<br />

Non Non-Household<br />

Non Household<br />

WEEE<br />

WEEE<br />

Country<br />

Country<br />

Annual<br />

Annual Frequency Frequency<br />

Frequency<br />

Joining<br />

Joining<br />

Renewal<br />

Renewal <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Fee<br />

Fee<br />

Required<br />

Required Reporting<br />

Reporting<br />

Deviations<br />

Deviations<br />

from<br />

from<br />

Reporting Reporting<br />

Reporting<br />

Under Under<br />

Under<br />

Categories<br />

Categories<br />

1-10 10<br />

B2B/<br />

B2B/<br />

B2C<br />

B2C Distributor Distributor Distributor Municipality Municipality Producer Producer Distributor Distributor Municipality Municipality Producer<br />

Producer<br />

split<br />

split<br />

Financing Financing<br />

Financing<br />

Structure<br />

Structure<br />

for for for hh<br />

hh<br />

WEEE WEEE WEEEb<br />

Historica Historicalc New<br />

New<br />

381<br />

FR Free No Half-yearly<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Also subcategories<br />

Yes � � � � � S2 R2 Producer<br />

GR - - - - � � S2 R1 Producer<br />

HU Yes No Annually None Yes � � - R1 Producer<br />

IE Yes Yes Monthly<br />

IT - - Annually<br />

Visible fee<br />

sub-category<br />

Also subcategories<br />

Yes � � � � S3 R1 Producer<br />

Yes � � � � - R1 Producer<br />

LT Free Yes Annually None No � � � � - R1 Producer<br />

LU - - Quarterly<br />

Also subcategories<br />

No � � � � S1 R1 Producer<br />

LV Free No Quarterly None No � � S2 R1 Producer<br />

NL Free No Bi-monthly<br />

Visible fee<br />

sub-category<br />

Yes � � � � S1 R2 Producer<br />

PL Yes Yes Quarterly None No � � - R1 Producer<br />

PT Yes Yes Half-yearly<br />

Also subcategories<br />

No � � � � � - R1 Producer


National National Register<br />

Register<br />

for for Producers<br />

Producers<br />

Reporting Reporting Requirements Requirements for<br />

for<br />

Producers<br />

Producers<br />

Responsibility Responsibility for for Household Household WEEE<br />

WEEE<br />

Physical Physical Responsibility<br />

Responsibility<br />

Financial Financial Responsibility Responsibility (ex (extended) (ex tended) (Infrastructure (Infrastructure set set-up). set set up).<br />

a<br />

Producer<br />

Producer<br />

Responsibility Responsibility for<br />

for<br />

Non Non-Household<br />

Non Household<br />

WEEE<br />

WEEE<br />

Country<br />

Country<br />

Annual<br />

Annual Frequency Frequency<br />

Frequency<br />

Joining<br />

Joining<br />

Renewal<br />

Renewal <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Fee<br />

Fee<br />

Required<br />

Required Reporting<br />

Reporting<br />

Deviations<br />

Deviations<br />

from<br />

from<br />

Reporting Reporting<br />

Reporting<br />

Under Under<br />

Under<br />

Categories<br />

Categories<br />

1-10 10<br />

B2B/<br />

B2B/<br />

B2C<br />

B2C Distributor Distributor Distributor Municipality Municipality Producer Producer Distributor Distributor Municipality Municipality Producer<br />

Producer<br />

split<br />

split<br />

Financing Financing<br />

Financing<br />

Structure<br />

Structure<br />

for for for hh<br />

hh<br />

WEEE WEEE WEEEb<br />

Historica Historicalc New<br />

New<br />

382<br />

SE Free Yes Annually None Yes � � - R1 Producer<br />

SI - - - - - � � � � S2 R1 Producer<br />

SK Free No Annually None No � � � � S1 R1 Producer<br />

UK Yes No Quarterly None Yes � � � � S2 R1 Producer<br />

Sources: United Nations University (2007) 2008 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Directive 2002/96 on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE) and Ökopol (2007) The<br />

Producer Responsibility Principle <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Directive, both reports produced for the European Commission.<br />

a The WEEE Directive indicates that producers are financially responsible for “at least” the collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE from collection-point onwards, leaving room for<br />

extended responsibility on municipalities, distributors or producers to finance the collection points for households e.g. via take-back schemes, storage<br />

points.<br />

b S1 - Finance WEEE collection, treatment etc. <strong>of</strong> their own products being placed on the market post 13 th August 2005.<br />

S2 - Allocation <strong>of</strong> financial responsibility is via their current market share.<br />

S3 - Producers that are members <strong>of</strong> an approved body are exempt from individual financial responsibility.<br />

c R1 - Producer responsible when replacing old-for-new. Otherwise end-user is responsible.<br />

R2 - The end-user is responsible for financing B2B WEEE.<br />

29/09/09


383<br />

� The financial structures associated with the WEEE regulations also vary<br />

according to country. Although producers are financially responsible for “at<br />

least” the collection <strong>of</strong> household WEEE from collection-point onwards, this<br />

leaves room for extended responsibility to draw upon municipalities,<br />

distributors or producers to finance the remaining set-up and running costs <strong>of</strong><br />

the household WEEE collection systems. The producer is responsible for these<br />

extended costs in Bulgaria, Cyprus, Spain, Finland, Greece, Hungary, Lithuania,<br />

Latvia, and Sweden, with Germany and Denmark assigning these costs to the<br />

municipality and Poland placing these costs on the distributor. Thus the<br />

municipalities <strong>of</strong> Germany and Denmark appear to take a larger portion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

overall responsibility for the delivery <strong>of</strong> WEEE policy than other MS;<br />

� There are two key categories <strong>of</strong> household WEEE for which producers are<br />

financially responsible: historical WEEE and new WEEE, with the former placed<br />

on the market prior to, and the latter after, 13 th August 2005. Considering that<br />

producers could not influence the design <strong>of</strong> products placed on the market<br />

before the Directive came into force, producers are assigned collective<br />

responsibility for historical WEEE, calculated according to their current market<br />

share. For new WEEE, the producer must bear individual financial<br />

responsibility and, since it cannot be assumed that all producers on the<br />

market today will remain on the market when their products are collected as<br />

WEEE, they must also provide a financial guarantee to ensure that these costs<br />

do not fall on other producers in the future. In countries such as Finland,<br />

Germany and the UK, financial responsibility for new WEEE is made through<br />

contributing to a collective pot, with payments calculated according to their<br />

current market share. This system usually provides sufficient financial<br />

guarantee should the company cease trading. In countries such as Belgium<br />

and the Netherlands, the producer pays specifically for the collection and<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> their own returned WEEE. In this instance, some form <strong>of</strong> financial<br />

guarantee is required (such as recycling insurance or blocked bank accounts)<br />

to account for the possibility that the company ceases trading in future; 427 and<br />

� In all countries, the producer is financially responsible for B2B WEEE placed on<br />

the market after 13 th August 2005. However, the producer may conclude<br />

contracts with end-users which stipulate other financing methods for B2B<br />

WEEE. Regarding historical B2B WEEE, the end-user is financially responsible<br />

in Germany, France and the Netherlands. In all other countries in the EU, the<br />

producer is financially responsible where any historical B2B is being<br />

exchanged for new EEE products on a like-for-like basis; the end-user is only<br />

financially responsible when they do not wish to replace the historical WEEE<br />

with a new like-for-like product.<br />

427 WEEE Forum, Guidance Document, [Accessed 8 th October 2008], available at http://www.weeeforum.org/doc/WEEE_Forum_Guidance_for_Compliance_En.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


20.2.1.1 Austria<br />

In Austria, the majority <strong>of</strong> household WEEE collections are undertaken via municipal<br />

collection sites. The majority <strong>of</strong> municipal sites (92.5 % as <strong>of</strong> 2006) are signed up to<br />

contracts with collective compliance schemes, with variable fees paid to those<br />

collection sites based on the amounts collected. Any municipal sites that are not<br />

signed up to contracts with collective schemes are entitled to lump sums based on<br />

the types <strong>of</strong> equipment collected and the size <strong>of</strong> the collection centre. The WEEE<br />

Coordination Body acts as a clearing house in Austria, assigning the pick-up and<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> any WEEE collected by municipalities and not covered by contracts. 428<br />

National legislation in Austria excludes retailers with sales areas less than 150 m 2<br />

from the obligation <strong>of</strong> taking back WEEE from consumers on a 1:1 basis. In addition,<br />

their legislation states that producers must set up at least one collection point per<br />

district. Reflecting their pre-WEEE directive legislation, WEEE in Austria must be<br />

sorted into five categories (large appliances, cooling equipment, CRTs, small<br />

appliances and gas discharge lamps). 428<br />

Implementation <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Directive in Austria requires that EEE is labelled correctly<br />

(crossed-out dustbin on wheels with line under it), that levels <strong>of</strong> hazardous<br />

substances are below those specified in the RoHS, and that all producers/distributors<br />

<strong>of</strong> EEE are registered.<br />

Prior to the WEEE Directive, Austria had only one collective system provider. However,<br />

the transposition <strong>of</strong> the Directive led to the creation <strong>of</strong> a more competitive<br />

environment by introducing four more collective producer systems and also allowing<br />

individuals to take on their own financial responsibility for WEEE. 429 In the collective<br />

systems, the provider makes an estimate <strong>of</strong> how many units will be sold within a<br />

particular time frame and the cost to collect and recycle those units is calculated and<br />

billed to the producer/distributor. The provider is then legally responsible to ensure<br />

that collection points are prepared to accept the products in question. Where the<br />

producers/distributors assume collection and recovery obligations by themselves,<br />

their products must be readily identifiable and they must conclude individual<br />

collection agreements with potential points <strong>of</strong> collection.<br />

20.2.1.2 Germany<br />

As in Austria, the municipality provides the main avenue for WEEE collection in<br />

Germany. The municipality is responsible for the collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE from<br />

householders and for the education <strong>of</strong> the public to source-separate this waste<br />

stream. Unlike many other EU countries, distributors are not obliged to provide a 1:1<br />

collection service in Germany (taking back an old product when a new one is<br />

428 http://www.buyusa.gov/austria/en/weeefaqs.html<br />

429 R. Veit (2005) How do WEEE get it right?, EMSNow, available at<br />

http://www.emsnow.com/npps/story.cfm?id=15184<br />

384<br />

29/09/09


purchased), though some <strong>of</strong>fer it voluntarily. 430 Thus the municipality bares a<br />

relatively large overall responsibility for WEEE compared to the majority <strong>of</strong> other MS.<br />

The EAR foundation centrally co-ordinates WEEE in Germany, assigning ‘pick-ups’ <strong>of</strong><br />

WEEE stored at municipal collection sites to producers that are based on an algorithm<br />

method. EAR also allows producers to deduct any individually-collected WEEE from<br />

their allocated share <strong>of</strong> WEEE that must be collected from the municipal collection<br />

sites. The producers must finance the containers, collection, treatment and recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> household WEEE. Germany has opted for full competition among producers<br />

regarding WEEE; consortia <strong>of</strong> EEE producers are allowed, but the competition<br />

authority has made it clear that it would oppose any consortia <strong>of</strong> producers whose<br />

market share <strong>of</strong> any EEE type exceeds 25 % (except for lamps). 431<br />

A financial guarantee is required from all producers. ElektroG provides producers the<br />

choice to finance WEEE collection either from their own products or via a calculated<br />

obligation that is based on the producer’s market share (as per historical WEEE<br />

financial responsibility allocation). The majority <strong>of</strong> producers choose to finance their<br />

new WEEE obligations based on their current market share <strong>of</strong> the total EEE quantity<br />

per equipment type, and provide a financial guarantee by participating in an<br />

appropriate funding system, such as recycling insurance or provision <strong>of</strong> a blocked<br />

bank account. This guarantee is then triggered only once the last remaining producer<br />

exits the market in a particular product group, with the consequent low risk equalling<br />

low premiums. Premiums in this system do not reflect the degree <strong>of</strong> difficulty <strong>of</strong><br />

subsequent recovery <strong>of</strong> the WEEE at the end <strong>of</strong> its life, being calculated only<br />

according to the amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE collected.<br />

20.2.1.3 Japan<br />

In April 2001, the Electrical Household Appliance Recycling Law (EHARL) took effect in<br />

Japan, with responsibility for refrigerators, washing machines, air conditioners and<br />

televisions shifted from local governments to producers. In Japan, retailers are now<br />

also obligated to take-back products at the end <strong>of</strong> their life and to transport them to<br />

producer stock-points. Contrary to the EU, consumers in Japan are notified <strong>of</strong> any<br />

recycling fees when they purchase EEE products, but are not required to pay the<br />

recycling fee until the point <strong>of</strong> disposal (typically when returning the WEEE to<br />

retailers). 432 This recycling fee only covers the cost <strong>of</strong> collection and pre-treatment,<br />

with any remaining cost met by the producer. The introduction <strong>of</strong> recycling fees in<br />

Japan has led to an increase in illegal dumping <strong>of</strong> WEEE, but also to a substantial<br />

increase in the second-hand market for EEE. As a consequence <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

430 LetsRecycle (2005) Germany implements the WEEE Directive, [Accessed 9 th October 2008],<br />

available at http://www.letsrecycle.com/news/archive/news.jsp?story=4222<br />

431 R. Veit (2005) How do WEEE get it right?, EMSNow, available at<br />

http://www.emsnow.com/npps/story.cfm?id=15184<br />

432 H. Aizawa, H. Yoshida and S-I. Sakai (2008) Current results and future perspectives for Japanese<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> home electrical appliances, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, 52, 1399-1410.<br />

385<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


the fee, the average lifespan <strong>of</strong> the television increased from 11.8 years to 12.5 years<br />

from 1997 to 2003. 433<br />

In order to promote good design in order to reduce the recycling fees required, the<br />

fees do not have to be uniform from company to company. However in reality,<br />

Matsushita Electric Industrial Co., Ltd was the first to set fees, and the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

companies have followed suit by setting their fees at the same level. In addition, most<br />

leading manufacturers <strong>of</strong> electric appliances have subsequently set up new recycling<br />

plants via alliances to process WEEE – as <strong>of</strong> 2002 there were 16 new recycling plants<br />

for this purpose. 433 Business consumers can either bring their WEEE to retailers and<br />

pay a fee, or treat WEEE as industrial waste at their own expense. 434 In rural areas,<br />

some municipalities still take care <strong>of</strong> WEEE on behalf <strong>of</strong> their householders, charging<br />

them for either taking the WEEE directly to a pre-treatment company, or returning<br />

them to aggregation points along with payment <strong>of</strong> the necessary fees.<br />

It is difficult to compare the Japanese and European systems, given that only four<br />

categories <strong>of</strong> WEEE are included in Japan, that the term ‘recycling rate’ in Japan only<br />

refers to any recycled material that is subsequently sold or taken back by someone<br />

free-<strong>of</strong>-charge (i.e. where the producer must pay to <strong>of</strong>fload the recycled materials, this<br />

does not count towards the recycling rate), and that the EU system currently sets a<br />

weight-based collection target rather than expressing their collection rate as a<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> the total WEEE in the system. For Japan, the recycling target for<br />

televisions has been set at 55 %, but in 2003 Japan was already exceeding this target<br />

by achieving a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 78 % (all at a positive monetary flow). 434 The Japanese<br />

system is also generally viewed as providing greater incentives for ‘eco-design’ <strong>of</strong> EEE<br />

because, as stated above, the manufacturers/producers are closely linked to<br />

recycling plants, with the consequent emergence <strong>of</strong> ‘design for disassembly’ and the<br />

‘automated disassembly using smart materials (ADSM). 435<br />

20.2.1.4 Norway<br />

Although Norway is not a member <strong>of</strong> the EU, it implemented its own WEEE policy back<br />

in 1998 entitled the “Reduction, Collection and Recovery <strong>of</strong> Electric and Electronic<br />

Appliances”. In 2006, this policy was revised to include the EU WEEE Directive<br />

requirement that all producers/distributors <strong>of</strong> EEE are registered. The WEEE policy in<br />

Norway applies to a slightly broader number <strong>of</strong> products than in the EU, including the<br />

distribution and metering <strong>of</strong> electric current and electromagnetic fields.<br />

433 M. Yamaguchi (2002) Extended Producer Responsibility in Japan – Introduction <strong>of</strong> “EPR” into<br />

Japanese <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> and some Controversy, Japanese Environmental <strong>Management</strong> Association for<br />

Industry, ECP Newsletter 19, pp 1-12.<br />

434 K. Sasaki (2004) Examining the <strong>Waste</strong> from Electrical and Electronic Equipment <strong>Management</strong><br />

Systems In Japan and Sweden, Master’s Thesis, Lund University, Sweden.<br />

435 Arcadis (2008) Study on RoHS and WEEE Directives, European Commission DG Enterprise and<br />

Industry March 2008.<br />

386<br />

29/09/09


In order to facilitate their financial responsibility for WEEE, every producer is required<br />

to be a member <strong>of</strong> a ‘take-back’ scheme. There are two national collection schemes<br />

in place in Norway: Elretur and Renas are responsible for the education, collection<br />

and processing <strong>of</strong> household and non-household WEEE respectively. In addition, other<br />

take-back schemes also exist, with all schemes requiring approval from the<br />

Norwegian Pollution Control Authority. Collection systems are via a series <strong>of</strong> collection<br />

points (including municipal facilities) and via distributor/retailer outlets. Distributors<br />

are obligated to inform customers that they can receive WEEE. Unlike a large number<br />

<strong>of</strong> EU countries, consumers can return WEEE to distributors without having to<br />

purchase a new product, as long as the distributor sells similar products. This<br />

approach is also in place in Switzerland and on a voluntary basis in Denmark.<br />

According to the Norwegian Pollution Control Authority, Norway was collecting<br />

approximately 28 kg WEEE per inhabitant in 2006, with 85 % <strong>of</strong> this collected WEEE<br />

subsequently re-used, recycled or used to generate energy. 436 According to the United<br />

Nations University report, this figure is somewhat lower at 13.41 kg per inhabitant per<br />

year. Either way, Norway remains one <strong>of</strong> the top performing countries discussed in<br />

this report.<br />

20.2.1.5 South Korea<br />

The ‘Act for Resource Recycling <strong>of</strong> Electrical/Electronic Products and Automobiles’<br />

came into force in South Korea in 2007, building on the previous Extended Producer<br />

Responsibility law <strong>of</strong> 2003. The aim <strong>of</strong> this Act was to establish a law to cover the<br />

entire product life cycle <strong>of</strong> EEE, to promote recycling and to ensure restrictions on the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> hazardous substance in product design. This Act follows a similar design to<br />

that <strong>of</strong> the EU, to ensure that manufacturers meet international standards and are<br />

able to continue exporting goods to the EU and elsewhere in the world. Eco-design is<br />

included in its requirements, with implementation geared towards continuous<br />

improvement in product design and recycling technology as and when these become<br />

technically and economically feasible. 437<br />

In Korea, the producers/importers <strong>of</strong> EEE must designate a collection depot for their<br />

products and inform their distributors <strong>of</strong> the chosen depot. When customers purchase<br />

new products, distributors are obliged to provide free take-back <strong>of</strong> old WEEE from the<br />

customer. Distributors can either arrange for the re-use <strong>of</strong> the WEEE themselves, or<br />

they must transport the collected WEEE to the designated collection depot. Producers<br />

may either take part in a collective scheme e.g. join a Recycling Mutual Aid<br />

Association, or may take individual producer responsibility for their EEE. 438<br />

436 Norwegian Pollution Control Authority (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment, [Accessed<br />

13 th October 2008], Available at http://www.environment.no/Tema/Avfall/<strong>Waste</strong>-electrical-andelectronic-equipment/<br />

437 J. Yoon (2007) Report on the Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Act for Resource Recycling <strong>of</strong> Electrical/Electric<br />

Products and Automobiles (Korea RoHS/ELV), available at http://www.koreahelpdesk.eu/rohs/korea/Ec<strong>of</strong>rontier_KoreaRoHS.pdf<br />

438 RSJ Consulting (2007) What is Korea “RoHS”?, available at<br />

http://www.rsjtechnical.com/WhatisKoreaRoHS.htm.<br />

387<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


There are, at present, certain specifics within the Act that require further decisions<br />

before it can become fully effective within South Korea. These decisions include<br />

which hazardous substances to restrict, the mandatory recycling rates that will be set<br />

for the various types <strong>of</strong> EEE (though the Act has already specified that these rates will<br />

be based on how much WEEE is separately collected compared to the yearly amount<br />

<strong>of</strong> EEE that is produced, as well as past performance records <strong>of</strong> recycling), and<br />

acceptable recycling methods and standards.<br />

20.2.1.6 Sweden<br />

In Sweden, until recently El-Kretsen has been the single national collective system for<br />

compliance with WEEE producer responsibility requirements. The collection system<br />

from householders has achieved the highest rate <strong>of</strong> collection reported in the EU,<br />

reaching 15.8 kg per capita per year in 2006. Collection is via WEEE containers at<br />

municipal collection sites, with municipalities providing storage space to accept WEEE<br />

from households. The provision and collection <strong>of</strong> these containers is financed by<br />

producers. There are currently over 1,000 collection sites in Sweden, with 700<br />

available for household and more than 300 available for non-household WEEE. El-<br />

Kretsen’s nationwide collection and recycling system currently also covers 5 % <strong>of</strong> EEE<br />

retailers and business consumers.<br />

The success <strong>of</strong> this collection system has been attributed to the level <strong>of</strong> cooperation<br />

between the partners, municipalities and contractors, plus the willingness <strong>of</strong> the<br />

public to participate in the separate collection. The system has also simplified how<br />

historical WEEE collection is financed, because there has been only one compliance<br />

scheme, removing the need to verify that each scheme is handling the required<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> historical WEEE.<br />

A new compliance solution is, however, currently emerging on the Swedish market<br />

that will mostly likely use an existing network <strong>of</strong> 2-3 large retailers for its collection<br />

system. In addressing the need for greater competition within the WEEE market in<br />

Sweden, the outcome should be lower costs <strong>of</strong> compliance, and hence, at the margin,<br />

lower product prices. 439 However, this additional compliance solution will add<br />

complexity to the system – with the probable need for a clearing house in order to<br />

apportion historical WEEE collection.<br />

Distributors in Sweden are not obligated to <strong>of</strong>fer WEEE take-back on a 1:1 basis due<br />

to the relatively strong performance <strong>of</strong> the municipal collection systems.<br />

Financial guarantees for the producer responsibility system can be <strong>of</strong>fered via<br />

recycling insurance, blocked bank accounts, an annual bank guarantee or via<br />

membership in collective finance systems. In Sweden, recycling insurances in<br />

particular are being used as a way <strong>of</strong> influencing product design. Whereas in<br />

countries such as Germany where the recycling insurance is only calculated according<br />

to the amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE production, in Sweden the insurance premiums are being<br />

adjusted to reflect a combination <strong>of</strong> the following: the projected future cost to recycle<br />

439 R. Veit (2005) How do WEEE get it right?, EMSNow, available at<br />

http://www.emsnow.com/npps/story.cfm?id=15184<br />

388<br />

29/09/09


that product, the risk that the materials will be classed as hazardous in the future, as<br />

any expected increases in efficiency <strong>of</strong> the recycling process, and projected future<br />

material revenues. 440 Thus premiums become lower where the company can<br />

demonstrate ease <strong>of</strong> recycling <strong>of</strong> their product, thereby providing financial incentive<br />

for companies to look for more environmentally-friendly product designs.<br />

20.2.1.7 Switzerland<br />

In 1998, the Swiss Government issued an Ordinance on the Return, the Taking Back<br />

and the Disposal <strong>of</strong> Electrical and Electronic Appliances (ORDEA), placing<br />

responsibilities on the consumer to return the product at the end <strong>of</strong> its life, and on the<br />

retailer to take back the product from the consumer free-<strong>of</strong>-charge. The Swiss<br />

Foundation for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (SENS) covers all categories listed in the EU<br />

directive except category three (IT and telecommunications) and category four<br />

(consumer equipment) products, which are covered by The Swiss Association for<br />

Information, Communication and Organisational Technology (SWICO). In addition, the<br />

Swiss Association for Illumination (SLG) operates a collective scheme for lighting<br />

equipment.<br />

Producers and importers have to pay an advanced recycling charge in Switzerland for<br />

every product that they place on the Swiss market. The charge is calculated based on<br />

the retail price. 441 Switzerland differs from the EU, because buyers pay an advanced<br />

advertised recycling fee on top <strong>of</strong> the purchase price which the producers/importers<br />

then use to pay their recycling charge and finance collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE.<br />

The consumer can return the WEEE to a distributor or other collection point free <strong>of</strong><br />

charge for processing. Similar to Norway, distributors are obliged to take-back similar<br />

EEE without the consumer having to purchase a new product. A disadvantage to this<br />

approach could be that certain distributors receive more than others. However a<br />

reimbursement is used in Switzerland to account for any imbalance, and the system<br />

has led to greater increases in take-back from distributors than from municipality<br />

collection sites in recent years.<br />

The ordinance does not specifically dictate whether companies must take<br />

responsibility via individual or collective means, but in reality most companies join a<br />

collective scheme. 442 There are approximately 450 <strong>of</strong>ficial collection points managed<br />

by SENS alone (including around 130 municipalities), 9000 retailers that accept takeback,<br />

and more than 30 treatment partners. 443<br />

440 Recycling M@gazine (2007) What if you could Eliminate the Risk? Insurances as a Way <strong>of</strong> Hedging<br />

Against Future Recycling Costs, Recycling M@gazine 12, 18-21.<br />

441 R. Veit (2005) How do WEEE get it right?, EMSNow, available at<br />

http://www.emsnow.com/npps/story.cfm?id=15184<br />

442 HKTDC (2006) WEEE and RoHS Transposition Update – Norway, Switzerland and Liechtenstein,<br />

Business Alert EU, [Accessed 13 th October 2008], available at<br />

http://info.hktdc.com/alert/eu0615d.htm<br />

443 SENS (2007) Swiss Foundation for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, [Accessed 13 th October 2008], available at<br />

www.sens.ch<br />

389<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


20.2.1.8 UK<br />

The UK regulations on WEEE came into force in January 2007. Obligated companies<br />

must register with an approved producer compliance scheme (PCS), which submits<br />

WEEE data to the Environment Agency on behalf <strong>of</strong> its clients and provides logistic<br />

solutions to fulfil collection and recycling obligations. Over 4,000 producers have now<br />

joined one <strong>of</strong> the 40 producer compliance schemes in the UK (figures from BERR).<br />

There is a network <strong>of</strong> designated collection facilities (DCFs) that accept WEEE from<br />

UK households free <strong>of</strong> charge; this network received financial support from retailers<br />

via a distributor take-back scheme which Valpak has been appointed to manage. All<br />

local authority civic amenity sites are designated DCFs. It should be noted that the<br />

level <strong>of</strong> support that the local authority civic amenity sites receive from Valpak was<br />

one <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> major hurdles which slowed the implementation <strong>of</strong> the UK<br />

regulations. Distributors <strong>of</strong> EEE must accept similar WEEE on a 1:1 basis.<br />

Treatment via accredited treatment facilities is also funded via PCSs. Originally a<br />

national allocation centre was meant to be set up to allocate designated collection<br />

facilities to PCSs, but this has since broken down, and PCSs now seek their own<br />

collection facilities. B2B is managed in similar fashion, but there is no distributor<br />

take-back scheme; most items should be collected free <strong>of</strong> charge by PCSs and sent to<br />

treatment facilities via funding from obligated companies. However in reality, despite<br />

the B2B arrangements, a large number <strong>of</strong> companies within the UK are not calling<br />

upon the producer to collect their WEEE, rather they are just paying to have mixed<br />

loads taken <strong>of</strong>f their hands.<br />

20.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

For the majority <strong>of</strong> countries listed in Section 20.2.1, varying degrees <strong>of</strong> both physical<br />

(infrastructure set-up) and financial responsibility exist between the producer,<br />

distributor and municipality. Combinations <strong>of</strong> responsibility are illustrated in Table<br />

20-1 for countries within the EU. The producer is named as financially responsible for<br />

the WEEE from “at least” collection-point onwards in the WEEE Directive; this leaves it<br />

open as to the extent to which responsibility for collection itself might rest with the<br />

municipality, the distributor or producer. There is clearly a need to finance the<br />

containers, storage space and collection-system required to collect WEEE from<br />

households. In countries such as Sweden and Finland, the producer is financially<br />

responsible for all aspects <strong>of</strong> WEEE collection, whereas in Germany the municipality<br />

takes on some <strong>of</strong> this financial responsibility and in Belgium, any additional financial<br />

responsibility rests with the distributor.<br />

Various combinations <strong>of</strong> physical responsibility also exist, with Germany again placing<br />

a greater degree <strong>of</strong> this responsibility on the municipality compared to countries such<br />

as Finland and Sweden, which require the producer and distributor to have greater<br />

responsibility for the set-up <strong>of</strong> WEEE collection infrastructure.<br />

In addition to the producer, distributor and municipality, various organisations provide<br />

both re-use and recycling support to WEEE policies. A number <strong>of</strong> organisations such<br />

as the previously mentioned EAR foundation in Germany and El Kretsen in Sweden<br />

facilitate collective responsibility for the recovery and disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE in these<br />

countries. Furthermore, a number <strong>of</strong> organisations focus specifically on the re-use <strong>of</strong><br />

390<br />

29/09/09


particular streams <strong>of</strong> WEEE. For example, Fonebak in the UK currently processes<br />

more than 250,000 mobile phones per month, with approximately 80 % being<br />

refurbished and sent to developing countries, and the remaining 20 % being sent for<br />

recycling. Fonebak has been granted licences by the Environment Agency and the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> for Business Enterprise and Regulatory Reform to operate as a Producer<br />

Compliance Scheme, an approved treatment facility, a designated collection facility<br />

and an approved exporter, thus providing an end-to-end solution for mobile phone<br />

producers. 444 Likewise, Computer Aid <strong>International</strong> refurbishes laptops and PCs,<br />

which are then used to support e-learning in countries such as Kenya, Madagascar<br />

and Zambia.<br />

Finally, the householder also plays an important role in the success <strong>of</strong> the WEEE<br />

policy. Householder participation was acknowledged by Sweden as one <strong>of</strong> the key<br />

reasons for their relatively high WEEE collection rates compared to other EU<br />

countries.<br />

20.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

Arcadis (2008) Study on RoHS and WEEE Directives, European Commission DG<br />

Enterprise and Industry, March 2008.<br />

Greenpeace (2008) Toxic Tech: Not in Our Backyard, Uncovering the Hidden Flows <strong>of</strong><br />

e-<strong>Waste</strong>.<br />

Ökopol (2007) The Producer Responsibility Principle <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Directive, Report<br />

produced for the European Commission.<br />

United Nations University (2007) 2008 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Directive 2002/96 on <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE), Final Report produced for the European<br />

Commission.<br />

20.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

Regarding waste prevention, the main aims <strong>of</strong> the WEEE policy were originally to<br />

provide the following key environmental benefits:<br />

391<br />

� Decline in the waste produced whilst manufacturing WEEE products as well as<br />

the minimisation <strong>of</strong> waste produced at the end <strong>of</strong> the product’s life, both <strong>of</strong><br />

which lead to a reduction in WEEE heading to landfill;<br />

� Encouragement <strong>of</strong> the re-use <strong>of</strong> WEEE by designing products that are reusable,<br />

long-lived, and capable <strong>of</strong> being readily remanufactured or refashioned;<br />

� Reduction in the leakage <strong>of</strong> potentially hazardous materials by controlling the<br />

toxicity <strong>of</strong> the product and ensuring its safe disposal (includes RoHS);<br />

444 Regenersis (2007) ‘WEEE Are Ready’ Say Mobile Phone Reuse and Recycling Leaders, 29 th June<br />

2007, available at:<br />

http://www.fonebak.com/WEEE%20Are%20Ready%20Say%20Mobile%20Phone%20Reuse%20and%2<br />

0Recycling%20Leaders.aspx<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


392<br />

� Avoidance <strong>of</strong> ozone-layer depleting substances. The net environmental gain<br />

from diverting products from disposal is consequently greatest for the<br />

Category 1B (cooling and freezing appliances) and lowest for Category 7 (toys<br />

etc);<br />

� Improvement in the environmental performance <strong>of</strong> products throughout their<br />

lifetime e.g. by making them more energy efficient or removing the stand-by<br />

mode.<br />

However in reality, it appears that the requirements listed in the WEEE Directive (see<br />

Section 20.1) focus on weight-based targets for recycling and re-use rather than on<br />

prevention; thus recycling has formed a significant driver for the national policies. The<br />

ability to take part in collective systems with financial responsibility based on market<br />

share rather than individual products has also contributed to the reduced incentive<br />

for producers to design their individual products with waste minimisation as a priority.<br />

Only the RoHS has readily provided for a reduction in the leakage <strong>of</strong> potentially<br />

hazardous materials from WEEE.<br />

Measurement <strong>of</strong> the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> WEEE policies as drivers for the prevention <strong>of</strong><br />

this waste stream are difficult, given that the only key reporting requirement to date<br />

with such policies has been the amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE that is collected for re-use, recycling<br />

or safe disposal. According to Arcadis (2008), there are limited conclusions to draw<br />

on the impact <strong>of</strong> the WEEE Directive on the share <strong>of</strong> company resources allocated to<br />

R&D within the EU. Direct consultations with industry stakeholders have suggested<br />

that the Directive has had limited influence over decisions to allocate resources to<br />

R&D in order to meet WEEE requirements. The significant number <strong>of</strong> drivers for ecodesign<br />

further complicates R&D decision-making. 445 In Japan, advances such as the<br />

automated disassembly using smart materials (ADSM) indicate that this policy system<br />

may be providing more incentives for design change and waste prevention, with the<br />

EEE manufacturers closely linked to the recycling installations. 446<br />

Rather than encouraging waste prevention, the WEEE policies in place appear to be<br />

more effective in terms <strong>of</strong> the recycling and correct disposal <strong>of</strong> products at the end <strong>of</strong><br />

their life, leading to a reduced burden on primary material stores and, in combination<br />

with RoHS, easier ability to recycle products and a reduction in the leakage <strong>of</strong><br />

hazardous and polluting substances during the disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE. It should be noted<br />

that WEEE is not a homogenous waste stream; its heterogeneity adds to the<br />

complexity <strong>of</strong> recovery, but also provides a number <strong>of</strong> materials that can be re-used,<br />

including metals, plastics and glass.<br />

The EU WEEE Directive currently sets a minimum collection target <strong>of</strong> 4 kg per annum<br />

per inhabitant.<br />

445 OECD (2006) EPR Policies and Product Design: Economic Theory and Selected Case Studies,<br />

Working Group on <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Recycling, Environment <strong>Policy</strong> Committee.<br />

446 Arcadis (2008) Study on RoHS and WEEE Directives, European Commission DG Enterprise and<br />

Industry, March 2008.<br />

29/09/09


Table 20-2 gives the amount <strong>of</strong> each category <strong>of</strong> WEEE collected according to country;<br />

the collection performance in the listed EU countries is similar to Norway and<br />

Switzerland for Category 1 WEEE, but Norway and Switzerland appear to perform<br />

better when collecting other categories <strong>of</strong> WEEE, with only Sweden providing<br />

comparable overall collection amounts. However, as noted in the UNU report, the<br />

current 4 kg target will be easier to reach in those countries that produce more EEE in<br />

the first place, rather than truly reflecting the re-use, recycling and safe disposal <strong>of</strong> all<br />

WEEE produced. The UNU report concludes that there is a rough correlation between<br />

relative affluence and the amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE generated, suggesting that in Western<br />

Europe WEEE arisings are in the region <strong>of</strong> 14-24 kg/head, while New Members are<br />

likely to be 6-12 kg/head.<br />

Table 20-2: Collection Performance (kg/inhabitant) by WEEE category<br />

Country<br />

393<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

WEEE Category Number<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10<br />

Japan 2.58 n.d. 0.82 n.d n.d n.d n.d n.d n.d n.d N/A<br />

Totals<br />

Norway 8.15 0.46 2.68 2.01 - - 0.04 0.06 - 0.01 13.41<br />

Switzerland 4.19 1.40 3.52 2.17 0.12 0.04 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 11.44<br />

Austria 2.00 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.1 Inc2 Inc2 Inc2 Inc2 Inc2 2.77<br />

Belgium 2.99 1.12 1.16 1.64 0.20 0.14 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.00 7.26<br />

Czech R 0.14 0.00 0.12 0.05 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.33<br />

Estonia 0.48 0.00 0.04 0.10 n.d. n.d. n.d. n.d. n.d. n.d. 0.63<br />

Finland 4.75 0.28 1.44 1.30 0.27 0.03 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.00 8.10<br />

Hungary 0.91 0.04 0.09 0.22 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.27<br />

Ireland 6.68 0.28 0.43 0.67 0.09 0.07 n.d. n.d. 0.00 n.d. 8.22<br />

Netherlands 2.59 0.53 n.d. 1.18 0.03 0.06 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.02 4.44<br />

Slovakia 0.35 0.04 0.05 0.20 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.66<br />

Sweden 5.01 1.41 2.54 2.36 0.74 0.11 0.02 0.02 n.d. n.d. 12.20<br />

UK 7.17 0.54 0.59 1.10 0.04 0.35 0.16 0.00 0.00 0.00 9.95<br />

EU average 3.11 0.42 0.65 0.88 0.14 0.08 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.00 5.31<br />

n.d. no data, Inc2 = included in Category 2 figure<br />

Source: United Nations University (2007) 2008 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Directive 2002/96 on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and<br />

Electronic Equipment (WEEE), Final Report produced for the European Commission.<br />

In addition, the 4 kg per household figure does not discriminate in favour <strong>of</strong> those<br />

products that have the highest economic or environmental relevance; for example,<br />

the collection <strong>of</strong> refrigerators containing CFCs is more important for meeting<br />

environmental objectives so the targets should be set to reflect this importance. The<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> CFC extraction from old appliances and disposal without emission to air was<br />

reported in Recycle.co.uk as only 42 % in Germany compared to 91 % in Austria,


stemming from a current lack <strong>of</strong> incentive to treat products in the most<br />

environmentally-friendly way if it requires further processing and added expense. 447<br />

The recent proposed revision to the EU WEEE Directive includes a change in collection<br />

targets from 4 kg per annum per inhabitant to a 65% collection rate, calculated<br />

according to the average amount <strong>of</strong> EEE placed on the market in the two preceding<br />

years. This proposed target is more in line with the current Japanese system. In<br />

addition, in order to encourage the re-use <strong>of</strong> whole appliances, it is proposed that<br />

such re-use be included within the 65 % target. In addition, the proposed revision<br />

presents the possibility <strong>of</strong> setting a separate collection rate for cooling and freezing<br />

equipment in 2012.<br />

Despite the figures presented in Table 20-2, it is estimated that only 25 % <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

arisings within the EU are currently being collected and treated, with no precise data<br />

available on what happens to the remaining 75%, termed ‘hidden flow’ in one<br />

Greenpeace report. 448 It is considered to be likely that some portion <strong>of</strong> this ‘hidden<br />

flow’ is being illegally exported to non-EU countries with lower treatment standards,<br />

leading to increased risk <strong>of</strong> the release <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances to the environment,<br />

an increase in the direct exposure <strong>of</strong> workers to hazardous substances associated<br />

with the ‘informal’ recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE in countries such as India and Thailand, as well<br />

as the loss <strong>of</strong> valuable secondary raw materials.<br />

Aside from the aforementioned problems associated with the current 4 kg collection<br />

target in the EU, this target also makes it difficult to analyse the effectiveness <strong>of</strong><br />

policy variations on the resultant recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE, because it does not determine<br />

the amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE that is subsequently disposed <strong>of</strong> as opposed to being re-used or<br />

recycled. In contrast, in Japan, recycling targets are set according to EEE placed on<br />

the market, and the term ‘recycling rate’ in Japan only refers to any material that is<br />

recovered without a negative balance (i.e. where the producer does not then have to<br />

pay a firm to recycle the material). The fact that Japan was, for example, already<br />

exceeding its 55 % target for the recycling <strong>of</strong> televisions in 2003 suggests that the<br />

Japanese system may be more effective than the current EU system in encouraging<br />

the re-use and recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE. Similarly, as reported by Greenpeace (2008), Sony<br />

in Japan are one <strong>of</strong> the few brands where a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 53% has been achieved,<br />

leaving a smaller ‘hidden flow’ than that found in the current EU system.<br />

Notwithstanding these data limitations, it seems reasonable to assume that though<br />

many <strong>of</strong> the original EU-15 have had little problem meeting a 4kg per inhabitant per<br />

annum target, the proposed 65% collection target is likely to prove far more<br />

challenging. Not only is this likely to require more comprehensive coverage by WEEE<br />

collection and take-back systems, but the need to demonstrate this through formal<br />

channels is likely to put pressure on Member States to reduce the export <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

through informal channels. This might not imply an end to exports per se, but would<br />

447 S. Flanagan (2008) UK recyclers should not follow German WEEE model, Recycle.co.uk: Don’t Bin<br />

it, Recycle it, available at: http://www.recycle.co.uk/news/614000.html<br />

448 Greenpeace (2008) Toxic Tech: Not in Our Backyard, Uncovering the Hidden Flows <strong>of</strong> e-<strong>Waste</strong>.<br />

394<br />

29/09/09


demand that the receiving facilities in third countries were shown to be operating to<br />

environmental standards broadly equivalent to those applied within the EU.<br />

20.6 Implementation Costs<br />

The financial model for WEEE producer responsibility will provide a key incentive for<br />

the degree to which producers will change the design <strong>of</strong> their products to try and<br />

minimise waste and facilitate easier recovery. As detailed in Table 20-2, the financial<br />

options available to EU producers vary according to MS; for household WEEE, some<br />

producers finance their responsibility individually via their own products being placed<br />

on the market (new WEEE), with historical WEEE obligations allocated via current<br />

market shares. In these circumstances, the producer is more likely to design their<br />

product with waste minimisation in mind, as they are directly responsible for their own<br />

WEEE. Some producers have the opportunity to take part in collective producer<br />

responsibility organisations (PROs) such as El Kretsen, which then organise the<br />

collection, treatment and disposal on the producer’s behalf. For non-household<br />

WEEE, the producer is financially responsible for any B2B WEEE placed on the market<br />

after 13 th August 2005. The end-user is financially responsible for financing all<br />

historical B2B WEEE in countries such as Germany, France and the Netherlands,<br />

whereas the producer is also financially responsible for historical WEEE in the<br />

remaining EU countries, so long as the customer is replacing old historical WEEE for<br />

new.<br />

It should be noted that, unlike the EU system, consumers in Japan are notified <strong>of</strong> any<br />

recycling fees when they purchase EEE products, but are not required to pay the<br />

recycling fee until the point <strong>of</strong> disposal (typically when returning the WEEE to<br />

retailers). 449 This recycling fee only covers the cost <strong>of</strong> collection and pre-treatment,<br />

with any remaining costs met by the producer.<br />

Financial Financial Financial guarantees<br />

guarantees<br />

Financial guarantees are required within WEEE policies (particularly for household<br />

WEEE), because it cannot be assumed that all producers that are in the market today<br />

will remain active in the market by the time their products are collected as WEEE<br />

(because some products have life-times <strong>of</strong> considerable length). Most MSs see<br />

membership in collective schemes as sufficient guarantee for those meeting their<br />

obligations via this channel i.e. producers will be responsible for other producers’<br />

products in the event that one member exits the market. For those producers wishing<br />

to comply individually, a blocked bank account or recycling insurance may also be<br />

used to satisfy the guarantee requirement. As discussed previously in Section 20.2.1,<br />

mechanisms such as recycling insurance vary from country to country, with Germany<br />

calculating premiums according to amounts <strong>of</strong> WEEE, compared to Sweden where<br />

premiums account for the ease <strong>of</strong> recycling the product at the end <strong>of</strong> its life.<br />

449 H. Aizawa, H. Yoshida and S-I. Sakai (2008) Current results and future perspectives for Japanese<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> home electrical appliances, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, 52, 1399-1410.<br />

395<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Throughout Europe, the costs <strong>of</strong> implementing WEEE policies varies widely,<br />

depending on a large number <strong>of</strong> factors as follows: 450<br />

396<br />

1. Some MS already had legislation in place concerning WEEE prior to the<br />

directive, therefore infrastructures and systems were already actively in place,<br />

reducing set-up costs to comply with the directive (e.g. Austria, Belgium,<br />

Denmark, Sweden and Luxembourg). It should be noted that, according to the<br />

UNU report, estimations for 2007 show costs to be decreasing over time, with<br />

anything up to a 27 % reduction in total costs for specific categories; 450<br />

2. The collection infrastructure currently in place e.g. the number <strong>of</strong> collection<br />

points that require servicing, the minimum amounts <strong>of</strong> WEEE to be collected,<br />

the geographical and traffic situation for transport costs, the number <strong>of</strong> staff at<br />

each collection point;<br />

3. Cost <strong>of</strong> permits for collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE;<br />

4. Treatment standards required by the MS;<br />

5. Enforcement <strong>of</strong> legislation on the export <strong>of</strong> WEEE to other countries i.e. how<br />

much WEEE ends up as ‘hidden flow’;<br />

6. Disposal costs e.g. landfill taxes, incineration etc;<br />

7. Possible pr<strong>of</strong>its for recovery <strong>of</strong> materials;<br />

8. Financial guarantee costs;<br />

9. Education/ awareness raising costs;<br />

10. Research and development costs;<br />

11. Reporting requirements; and<br />

12. The market situation: where a monopolistic system exists (as was the<br />

situation in Sweden until recently) there is less competition, resulting in more<br />

costly products for the consumer.<br />

Table 20-3 shows a breakdown <strong>of</strong> the range <strong>of</strong> total costs associated with the various<br />

categories <strong>of</strong> WEEE across the MS and Table 20-4 shows the costs for the longer<br />

running compliance schemes. These tables illustrate the point that where systems<br />

have been in place for longer, the range <strong>of</strong> costs and the average cost tends to<br />

decline.<br />

450 United Nations University (2007) 2008 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Directive 2002/96 on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and<br />

Electronic Equipment (WEEE), Final Report produced for the European Commission.<br />

29/09/09


Table 20-3: Range <strong>of</strong> Total Costs for WEEE across the Member States<br />

Category <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

397<br />

Total Costs (€/t)<br />

MIN MAX<br />

1a LHHA - 933.16<br />

1b C&F 194.00 880.37<br />

2 SHA 138.56 1,246.03<br />

3a IT ex CRT 135.38 1,703.56<br />

3b IT CRT 164.00 1,393.65<br />

4a CE ext CRT 138.56 1,328.47<br />

4b CE CRT 164.00 1,393.65<br />

5 Light 555.78 2,568.62<br />

6 Tools 204.09 1,043.99<br />

7 Toys 390.42 610.49<br />

8 Medical 168.35 562.24<br />

9 M&C 253.26 1,382.48<br />

10 Aut. Disp. 254.63 483.99<br />

Source: United Nations University (2007) 2008 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Directive 2002/96 on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and<br />

Electronic Equipment (WEEE), Final Report produced for the European Commission.<br />

Table 20-4: Total WEEE costs per product category for long running schemes (fully<br />

operative pre-2005 and having at least 3 data sets for definition <strong>of</strong> minimum,<br />

maximum and average costs).<br />

Category<br />

Total Costs (€/t)<br />

MIN MAX<br />

AVERAGE<br />

1a LHHA<br />

54.46 457.90 235.31<br />

1b C&F<br />

338.46 811.49 557.70<br />

2 SHA<br />

272.44 499.21 383.13<br />

3a IT ex CRT<br />

272.08 539.23 379.69<br />

3b IT CRT<br />

349.26 621.48 499.29<br />

4a CE ext CRT<br />

254.48 549.37 422.12<br />

4b CE CRT<br />

428.55 621.41 528.01<br />

5 Light<br />

561.15 840.00 662.83<br />

6 Tools<br />

220.83 341.49 300.79<br />

7 Toys<br />

409.56 609.16 495.15<br />

8 Medical<br />

238.64 529.79 409.64<br />

Source: United Nations University (2007) 2008 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Directive 2002/96 on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and<br />

Electronic Equipment (WEEE), Final Report produced for the European Commission.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


20.7 Complementary Policies<br />

398<br />

� Directive 2002/95/EC on the Restriction <strong>of</strong> Hazardous Substances (RoHS)<br />

must also be considered as a policy driver alongside producer responsibility for<br />

WEEE in the EU; the RoHS Directive aims to minimise the use <strong>of</strong> certain<br />

hazardous materials in newly-produced EEE and to minimise the release <strong>of</strong><br />

hazardous substances into the environment by controlling the disposal route<br />

<strong>of</strong> older equipment at the end <strong>of</strong> its life. Producers must provide evidence that<br />

the concentrations <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials are below defined levels. The six<br />

key restricted substances are lead, cadmium, mercury, hexavalent chromium,<br />

polybrominated biphenyls and polybrominated diphenyl. Similar regulations to<br />

the RoHS exist in those non-EU countries that have their own WEEE<br />

regulations e.g. Japan, South Korea;<br />

� The Energy-Using Products (EuP) Directive 2005/32/EC, which came into force<br />

in August 2007 and which provides a framework for the setting <strong>of</strong> eco-design<br />

requirements for any group <strong>of</strong> products which use energy (including EEE). This<br />

directive seeks to make energy efficiency improvements rather than having a<br />

direct focus on waste. However, ensuing product designs which make energy<br />

efficiency improvements may also extend the product’s life, thus contributing<br />

indirectly to the prevention <strong>of</strong> WEEE;<br />

� The EU Batteries and Accumulators and <strong>Waste</strong> Batteries and Accumulators<br />

Directive (2006/66/EC), which aims to improve the environmental<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> batteries and <strong>of</strong> the activities <strong>of</strong> all economic operators<br />

involved in the life cycle <strong>of</strong> batteries. A producer <strong>of</strong> EEE is also regarded as a<br />

battery producer if the appliance placed on the market has a battery inside.<br />

The Batteries Directive limits the use <strong>of</strong> mercury and cadmium in all batteries<br />

by weight, prohibits the disposal by landfill or incineration <strong>of</strong> waste industrial<br />

and automotive batteries, and sets recycling rates to ensure that a high<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> the weight <strong>of</strong> waste batteries is recycled (65% <strong>of</strong> lead acid<br />

batteries, 75% <strong>of</strong> nickel-cadmium batteries and 50% <strong>of</strong> other waste batteries).<br />

Batteries that are incorporated in WEEE will be collected on the basis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

WEEE Directive and then removed from the electronic equipment, counting<br />

towards the collection targets <strong>of</strong> the Batteries Directive;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> Shipments Regulations: in the EU, for example, the export <strong>of</strong> WEEE is<br />

only permitted for recovery and is controlled by EU Shipment Regulations. In<br />

addition, the Basel Convention on the Control for the Transboundary<br />

Movement <strong>of</strong> Hazardous <strong>Waste</strong>s and Their Disposal, in force since 1992, is<br />

the only global environment agreement on waste, comprising more than 165<br />

national governments. This global agreement regulates trade in hazardous<br />

wastes, including WEEE, looking to ensure its safe disposal and that the<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> such wastes is minimised.<br />

20.8 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The number <strong>of</strong> collective schemes in operation within a country and the resultant<br />

competition influences the overall cost <strong>of</strong> implementing the WEEE policy. A report by<br />

Veit compared the current waste management system charges in twelve MS for a<br />

washing machine (38 kg), food processor (3.5 kg), laptop (1.5 kg), DVD player (1.8<br />

29/09/09


kg), and a TV (15 kg), finding the average WEEE cost <strong>of</strong> these products to be<br />

€5.34. 451 In monopolistic environments, the average product had a €6.33 WEEE<br />

charge attached to it, which was found to be more than double the €2.93 charge in<br />

competitive environments. Nonetheless, monopolistic environments may be the best<br />

way to get new infrastructure in place for the more recent WEEE implementation in<br />

some MS.<br />

According to a report by OECD, 452 there is limited evidence to support the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

pricing on the demand for EEE. However, this is difficult to believe. In theory, the<br />

higher product price resulting from WEEE producer responsibility should lead to a<br />

reduction in the quantity demanded, even if only at the margin. The issue, therefore,<br />

is that given the relatively high cost <strong>of</strong> most EEE compared to the average additional<br />

WEEE cost given above (€5.34), it is likely that price increases are too small to have<br />

any significant influence on demand. In addition, even if the elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand was<br />

-0.2, a 5 % increase in price gives at most a 1 % reduction in demand, whilst there<br />

remains an overall rising trend in EEE consumption worldwide. Hence, though<br />

difficult to discern, there probably is a pricing effect on the demand for EEE. However,<br />

this effect is simply very small, owing to the relatively small impact on product prices<br />

and the inelastic nature <strong>of</strong> demand for most EEE items.<br />

20.9 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The UNU and Greenpeace reports note that there is ‘leakage’ in the current WEEE<br />

system throughout Europe and worldwide, particularly concerning items <strong>of</strong> value such<br />

as large domestic appliances that contain a lot <strong>of</strong> metals, and IT and telecoms<br />

equipment such as desktop computers and mobile phones. WEEE may escape the<br />

proper management system via illegal exports or via back-door sales to unlicensed<br />

operators, both less-equipped to manage WEEE in an environmentally-sound manner.<br />

The UNU report gives the following examples:<br />

399<br />

� Shipments <strong>of</strong> WEEE disguised as goods from Hamburg port (DEUTSCHE<br />

UMWELTHILFE 2007);<br />

� 28 % <strong>of</strong> businesses found to be exporting WEEE illegally from the Netherlands<br />

(VROM 2007).<br />

As discussed previously in Section 20.5, it is estimated that only 25% <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

arisings within the EU are currently being collected and treated, with no precise data<br />

available on what happens to the remaining 75%. 453 It is considered to be likely that<br />

some portion <strong>of</strong> this ‘hidden flow’ is being illegally exported to non-EU countries. In<br />

addition, ‘free-riders’ in the system also contribute to the ‘hidden flow, with VROM<br />

451 R. Veit (2005) How do WEEE get it right?, EMSNow, available at<br />

http://www.emsnow.com/npps/story.cfm?id=15184<br />

452 OECD (2006) EPR Policies and Product Design: Economic Theory and Selected Case Studies,<br />

Working Group on <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Recycling, Environment <strong>Policy</strong> Committee.<br />

453 Greenpeace (2008) Toxic Tech: Not in Our Backyard, Uncovering the Hidden Flows <strong>of</strong> e-<strong>Waste</strong>.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


estimating that 15 % <strong>of</strong> the WEEE stream is not being collected due to free-riders who<br />

sell EEE but do not honour their take-back obligations.<br />

The UNU report suggests specific options to enhance compliance with the policy:<br />

400<br />

� Mandatory hand in <strong>of</strong> all separately collected WEEE at certified compliance<br />

schemes, to reduce ‘cherry-picking’ <strong>of</strong> the better quality WEEE prior to reprocessing<br />

and ensure proper treatment. The main disadvantages <strong>of</strong> this<br />

approach are that WEEE re-use may suffer at the expense <strong>of</strong> increased<br />

recycling, and that there will be increased enforcement burden on competent<br />

bodies, with the need for validated input/output data from collection points.<br />

Instead <strong>of</strong> a compensation payment for storage and collection efforts <strong>of</strong> the<br />

producer, this approach may be reinforced if the producer were handed a<br />

reimbursement or payment for handing over the WEEE.<br />

� Changing the ‘take-back’ mechanism at retail shops so that instead <strong>of</strong> the oldfor-new<br />

policy, consumers can hand in an old product at any retail shop that is<br />

currently selling equipment in the same category, without having to purchase a<br />

new product. This approach is already in place in Norway and Switzerland and<br />

is applied on a voluntary basis in Denmark. A disadvantage to this approach<br />

could be that certain retailers receive more than others, but this could be<br />

compensated for by a reimbursement or volume-based payment. The use <strong>of</strong> a<br />

reimbursement approach in Switzerland has led to greater take-back<br />

increases from retailers than from municipality collection sites.<br />

Examples <strong>of</strong> specific enforcement measures in particular countries are as follows:<br />

� In Sweden, a fine may be imposed on anyone that fails to fulfil obligations <strong>of</strong><br />

the WEEE policy, including failure to label EEE items correctly and failure to<br />

supply the required data regarding WEEE. Individuals that infringe the RoHS<br />

legislation may also receive a fine or a term <strong>of</strong> imprisonment not exceeding<br />

two years. Where the <strong>of</strong>fence is more serious (particularly regarding RoHS) and<br />

could have, or did cause damage, the individual will receive between 6 months<br />

and 6 years imprisonment. Fines are calculated according to the nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

infringement, the means <strong>of</strong> the individual, and the seriousness <strong>of</strong> the incident.<br />

Under the WEEE legislation, it is possible to impose an environmental fine<br />

when an individual fails to register and still sells EEE products, or fails to<br />

inform the Environmental Protection Agency <strong>of</strong> how the products are collected<br />

and treated.<br />

� Similar penalties also apply in Austria and Norway. In Austria, failure to comply<br />

with the WEEE regulations generally leads to a fine (ranging from €360 to<br />

€7,270), with a minimum fine <strong>of</strong> €1,800 where the individual in question is<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>essionally active in the area <strong>of</strong> waste management. Administrative fines<br />

may also be applied if the individual fails to provide the necessary<br />

documentation, data or has not registered. In Norway, non-compliance with<br />

the WEEE and RoHS regulations is subject to fines under the terms <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Product Control Act. Penalties associated with WEEE can include fines,<br />

imprisonment for a term not exceeding three months, or both, unless more<br />

stringent penalty provisions apply. Penalties for infringement <strong>of</strong> the RoHS will<br />

only be applied if the infringement is shown to be wilful or the result <strong>of</strong> gross<br />

negligence.<br />

29/09/09


20.10 Lessons Learned<br />

Administrative Administrative burden<br />

burden<br />

The administrative burden on individual businesses should be considered when<br />

designing producer responsibility systems – the need for reporting to counteract freeriding<br />

is acknowledged, but the requirements should be balanced and should be<br />

considered according to the product in question and the consistency <strong>of</strong> the markets<br />

for that product. The use <strong>of</strong> collective compliance schemes reduces the individual<br />

burdens placed on businesses. In addition, the development <strong>of</strong> and investment in IT<br />

infrastructure would help reduce the economic impact <strong>of</strong> reporting requirements,<br />

though this possibility is typically unaffordable for SMEs.<br />

According to the UNU report, there are currently large differences in the number <strong>of</strong><br />

registered producers according to MS within the EU, resulting from differences in the<br />

‘definition’ <strong>of</strong> producers, the role <strong>of</strong> distributors and the impact <strong>of</strong> SME awareness <strong>of</strong><br />

their obligations and the need to be registered. Industry across Europe has raised the<br />

issue <strong>of</strong> ‘free-riding’, particularly regarding SMEs and their lack <strong>of</strong> awareness. In<br />

addition, different obligations to register B2B compared to B2C has led to some<br />

producers registering their products only as B2B, even when placing the product on a<br />

B2C channel (especially where no clear definitions <strong>of</strong> B2B compared to B2C exits) to<br />

avoid these obligations.<br />

Differing reporting requirements (see Table 20-1) also place differing financial<br />

burdens on the overall WEEE system. The higher the frequency <strong>of</strong> reporting, the<br />

higher the number <strong>of</strong> hours required to report and, consequently, the higher the<br />

economic and administrative burdens. The majority <strong>of</strong> registered producers see the<br />

need for reporting (particularly to try and track free-riding), but a high percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

stakeholders are experiencing a burden in carrying out such reporting. If financial<br />

obligations are to be decided according to amounts <strong>of</strong> products placed on the<br />

markets, the frequency <strong>of</strong> reporting should also be product-specific as some markets<br />

fluctuate throughout the year. In addition, varying definitions <strong>of</strong> B2B compared to B2C<br />

currently determine different financial obligations in different countries.<br />

The proposed revision to the EU WEEE Directive includes the requirement to<br />

harmonise both the registration and reporting obligations for producers between the<br />

national producer registers, including making the registers inter-operational (i.e.<br />

between countries). In addition, clarification <strong>of</strong> the distinction between B2B and B2C<br />

WEEE, through a comitology procedure, will further clarify which products fall under<br />

the legislation and the obligations that apply to different EEE producers.<br />

Awareness<br />

Awareness<br />

There is a need to increase the awareness <strong>of</strong> WEEE regulations for both businesses<br />

(particularly SMEs) and the public. Low WEEE return rates are partly the result <strong>of</strong> a<br />

lack <strong>of</strong> awareness and sometimes also a willingness <strong>of</strong> the consumer/ end-user to<br />

actively participate in WEEE take-back systems. It may also help if consumers were to<br />

know what they are paying for when they buy a product (e.g. visible fees) to ensure<br />

their contribution to take-back system performances. A survey undertaken <strong>of</strong> more<br />

than 2,000 people in the UK by an electrical retailer (Comet) found that only 2% <strong>of</strong><br />

people knew about the WEEE Directive. 71 % had no idea what the logo that is<br />

displayed on new electrical products to show it should be recycled actually meant<br />

401<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


(with almost 1 in 5 people thinking it meant “no wheelie bin collection in this area”)<br />

and just under half <strong>of</strong> the people surveyed had never recycled an electrical product.<br />

Col Collection Col Collection<br />

lection points points<br />

In order to encourage higher collection rates <strong>of</strong> WEEE, retailers should provide good<br />

accessible collection points as far as possible, forming a strong bridge between<br />

consumers and producers. In addition, the take-back <strong>of</strong> old products by retailers<br />

without the need for the consumer to purchase something new has been found to be<br />

successful in increasing collection rates in Norway, Denmark and Switzerland.<br />

Municipalities should also enable good accessible collection points alongside retailers<br />

where possible, ideally with no costs falling on the municipality for such collection<br />

(through appropriate payments made to them). The UK system is an interesting one,<br />

but it must be questioned whether payments to local authorities really cover the full<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> their role in WEEE collection.<br />

Exports<br />

Exports<br />

The large amount <strong>of</strong> ‘hidden flows’ <strong>of</strong> WEEE indicate that, despite the current<br />

legislation in place regarding exports <strong>of</strong> WEEE and hazardous materials, a significant<br />

amount is still being illegally exported, ending up in countries with lower treatment<br />

standards, with workers in these countries within the more informal recycling sectors<br />

ending up exposed to high levels <strong>of</strong> toxic substances. 454<br />

In order to reduce the ‘hidden flows’ passing between countries, the EU WEEE policy<br />

revision recommends that producers should take full ownership <strong>of</strong> the collection <strong>of</strong><br />

WEEE, particularly the financing <strong>of</strong> its collection throughout the whole waste chain, to<br />

avoid leakage <strong>of</strong> WEEE to sub-optimal treatment and illegal exports, as well as<br />

shifting payment for the collection <strong>of</strong> this waste from the general tax payer to the<br />

consumer. It may well be that this becomes necessary, in any case, in order to ensure<br />

the new 65% collection target is met.<br />

Financial Financial Mechanisms<br />

Mechanisms<br />

Financial mechanisms such as variable recycling insurance premiums associated with<br />

products being easier to recycle, or reduced fees attached to products which when<br />

treated in a certain way are less environmentally-damaging, should be further<br />

explored as ways <strong>of</strong> delivering the ‘changing design <strong>of</strong> products resulting in waste<br />

prevention’ aim <strong>of</strong> WEEE policies. In addition, in allowing producers to pay specifically<br />

for the collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> their own returned WEEE, rather than meeting<br />

their financial responsibility as part <strong>of</strong> a collective system based on market shares,<br />

there will also be an increased incentive for producers to design their individual<br />

products with waste minimisation as a priority.<br />

Historical Historical WEEE<br />

WEEE<br />

454 Greenpeace (2008) Toxic Tech: Not in Our Backyard, Uncovering the Hidden Flows <strong>of</strong> e-<strong>Waste</strong>.<br />

402<br />

29/09/09


Historical and ‘orphan’ waste, whose producers have gone out <strong>of</strong> business, must be<br />

dealt with within the WEEE policy system - for example, by making existing producers<br />

responsible for such WEEE according to their respective market share. 455<br />

Individual Individual Individual or or Collective Collective Take Take-Back Take Back Back Schemes<br />

Although the first generation <strong>of</strong> WEEE policies have typically involved collective takeback<br />

schemes e.g. El-Kretsen in Sweden, there is now increasing interest in individual<br />

take-back programmes. According to a report by OECD, the increasing focus on<br />

individual schemes has been advocated by some significant market players; for<br />

example, Hewlett Packard has argued that any US state laws aiming to use some<br />

form <strong>of</strong> collective take-back approach should also allow opt-out by individual<br />

companies that can demonstrate that they have their own take-back and recycling<br />

programmes. 455 This argument is based on the thinking that the company’s own<br />

approaches will be more cost-effective than the collective state-government<br />

sponsored systems, and that where companies take efforts to improve the design <strong>of</strong><br />

their products for recycling and re-use, or to minimize materials use, then they will<br />

benefit directly from these efforts (rather than the benefits being spread across all<br />

producers in a collective scheme). Similar thinking has also led to the collective<br />

European arrangement <strong>of</strong> HP, Electrolux, Braun and Sony, to provide competition to<br />

existing collective organisations in Europe whilst still achieving some economies <strong>of</strong><br />

scale.<br />

An individual system may provide more direct incentives for ‘design for environment’<br />

(DfE) activities such as increasing the ability to recycle components within the<br />

products, but it may also be more difficult for the government to monitor the activities<br />

<strong>of</strong> many individual companies, and it is also likely to be more difficult to achieve<br />

economies <strong>of</strong> scale than in a collective system. As such, this option is more likely to<br />

be available to major players than smaller ones (though it should be noted that the<br />

electronics sector is, for many product categories, dominated by a relatively small<br />

number <strong>of</strong> firms). Collective environments may also be the best way to get new<br />

infrastructure in place for more recent WEEE schemes. Nonetheless, as advocated by<br />

Hewlett Packard and many systems currently in place within the EU (see Table 20-1),<br />

it may be prudent to leave the option open for individual take-back schemes to<br />

develop.<br />

Targets<br />

Targets<br />

As noted by Greenpeace (2005), 456 mandatory re-use and recycling targets are a key<br />

element <strong>of</strong> encouraging the recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE. In addition, the stipulation that Energy<br />

from <strong>Waste</strong> be excluded from ‘recycling’ targets should also be considered, in order to<br />

455 OECD (2006) EPR Policies and Product Design: Economic Theory and Selected Case Studies,<br />

Working Group on <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Recycling, Environment <strong>Policy</strong> Committee.<br />

456 Greenpeace (2005) Toxic Tech: Pulling the Plug on Dirty Electronics, Extended Producer<br />

Responsibility.<br />

403<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


try to provide greater incentives for producers to design products with reuse/recycling<br />

in mind.<br />

The review by the United Nations University (2007) highlights the following key points<br />

regarding WEEE targets in Europe:<br />

404<br />

� The WEEE directive currently sets a minimum collection target target target <strong>of</strong> 4 kg per<br />

annum per inhabitant; however, this figure does not discriminate in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

those products that have the highest economic or environmental relevance;<br />

for example, the collection <strong>of</strong> refrigerators containing CFCs is more important<br />

for meeting environmental objectives so the targets should be set to reflect<br />

this importance. The rate <strong>of</strong> CFC extraction from old appliances and disposal<br />

without emission to air was reported in Recycle.co.uk as only 42 % in Germany<br />

compared to 91 % in Austria, stemming from a current lack <strong>of</strong> incentive to<br />

treat products in the most environmentally-friendly way if it requires further<br />

processing and added expense; 457<br />

� In addition, for some categories <strong>of</strong> WEEE it appears that the targets are easily<br />

being being met met by a number <strong>of</strong> European MS – for instance the current shredding<br />

and separation technologies for white goods typically lead to recycling rates in<br />

excess <strong>of</strong> those prescribed. It would have been appropriate, prior to the<br />

revision in the target, to ask the question whether the targets are high enough<br />

in those countries for which WEEE policy is now well developed, and where<br />

large (and growing) quantities <strong>of</strong> WEEE are found in the waste stream;<br />

� The final destination <strong>of</strong> the recycled/ recovered WEEE is not considered in the<br />

targets, and may thus result in discrimination against more environmentallypreferred<br />

options where they require more processing. For example, the use <strong>of</strong><br />

cleaned CRT glass for producing new CRTs has been shown to be more<br />

resource and energy efficient than using the glass as road filling material.<br />

However, WEEE policy regards both destinations as having equal footing in<br />

recycling percentages. Thus companies may favour road filling as the final<br />

destination as this requires less cleaning and separation;<br />

� Weight-based recycling targets may divert attention away from ‘prevention’ as<br />

a key policy outcome, by discouraging the design <strong>of</strong> future EEE to use less<br />

material and to reduce environmental damage in favour <strong>of</strong> meeting such<br />

targets.<br />

The recent proposed revision to the EU WEEE Directive includes a change in collection<br />

targets from 4 kg per annum per inhabitant to a 65% collection rate, calculated<br />

according to the average amount <strong>of</strong> EEE placed on the market in the two preceding<br />

years. This proposed target is more in line with the current Japanese system. In<br />

addition, in order to encourage the re-use <strong>of</strong> whole appliances, it is proposed that<br />

such re-use be included within the 65% target. The proposed revision also presents<br />

the possibility <strong>of</strong> setting a separate collection rate for cooling and freezing equipment<br />

457 S. Flanagan (2008) UK recyclers should not follow German WEEE model, Recycle.co.uk: Don’t Bin<br />

it, Recycle it, available at: http://www.recycle.co.uk/news/614000.html<br />

29/09/09


in 2012. Hence, the revision may improve performance in a variety <strong>of</strong> ways, as hinted<br />

at above.<br />

405<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


21.0 Producer Responsibility, WEEE - Germany<br />

21.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

According to the Electrical and Electronic Equipment Act (Elektro- and<br />

Elektronikgerätegesetz - ElektroG) producers are obliged to take back waste electrical<br />

and electronic equipment (WEEE) and either reuse, recycle or dispose <strong>of</strong> the collected<br />

items according to ecological standards. 458<br />

The aims <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG - being identical to the WEEE-Directive and RoHS – are:<br />

406<br />

� to prevent and reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE;<br />

� to reduce waste volumes through reuse and through provisions for collection,<br />

recovery and recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE;<br />

� to reduce the content <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances in equipment; and<br />

subsequently; and<br />

� to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances in the residual waste by<br />

banning the disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE via the residual waste stream.<br />

The ElektroG contains different regulations for WEEE from the commercial sector<br />

(B2B) compared to from private households (B2C). These are set out below.<br />

Collection Collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> WEEE WEEE from from commercial commercial sector (B2B)<br />

According to Art. 10 para 2, ElektroG producers are responsible for the disposal <strong>of</strong><br />

WEEE from the purely commercial sector, provided it is electrical and electronic<br />

equipment that is placed on the market after 13 th August 2005. End-users are<br />

responsible for equipment placed on the market before 13 August 2005. Producers<br />

and users may reach an agreement which departs from the aforementioned<br />

provisions. The party responsible for disposal shall either reuse WEEE or its<br />

components, treat or dispose <strong>of</strong> it in compliance with the provisions <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG,<br />

and shall bear the costs <strong>of</strong> disposal.<br />

The definition <strong>of</strong> B2B equipment depends, in practice, on whether the equipment is<br />

used exclusively by businesses, and is determined by the characteristics <strong>of</strong> the<br />

equipment (e.g. the type and place <strong>of</strong> use, special pre-conditions for the use <strong>of</strong> the<br />

equipment, qualified personnel). The distribution channels (e.g. delivery only to<br />

commercial distributors) are not relevant for classification as B2B equipment.<br />

B2B equipment shall not be delivered to local authority public collection sites and<br />

collected with WEEE from private households, and therefore will not pr<strong>of</strong>it from the<br />

free <strong>of</strong> charge take-back obligations. Producers are not obliged to collect B2B<br />

458 Act Governing the Sale, Return and Environmentally Sound Disposal <strong>of</strong> Electrical and Electronic<br />

Equipment, as <strong>of</strong>: 23 rd March 2005, Federal Law Gazette BGBl. I, p. 762.<br />

29/09/09


equipment. Furthermore producers do not have to pay a financial guarantee for the<br />

B2B equipment at the EAR (see Section 21.3).<br />

Collection Collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> WEEE WEEE WEEE from from from private private private households households households (B2C)<br />

(B2C)<br />

Since 24 th March 2006, the disposer (consumer) <strong>of</strong> WEEE has been obliged to<br />

discard their WEEE in a system which is separated from the residual waste stream. 459<br />

Public waste management authorities remain responsible for the collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

from private households. The procedure for collection is widely at the discretion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

local authorities, though they must ensure that private households can return WEEE<br />

free <strong>of</strong> charge (bring-back system). The number <strong>of</strong> collection points to be set up and<br />

the combination <strong>of</strong> bring sites and kerbside collections is based on population<br />

density, other local conditions and the waste management objective <strong>of</strong> the greatest<br />

possible level <strong>of</strong> collection. Smaller municipalities may set up a joint collection point.<br />

A dealer that has taken over equipment (e. g. a washing machine) from a private<br />

household may also return this equipment free <strong>of</strong> charge to the collection point <strong>of</strong> the<br />

respective local authority. The local authorities may re-finance the costs for collection<br />

via waste charges.<br />

Local authorities are required to hold the WEEE available for collection by producers,<br />

separated into five groups (containers). Classification into the five groups is decided<br />

on the basis <strong>of</strong> technical disposal considerations. The five categories are:<br />

407<br />

� large household appliances and automatic dispensers (Category 1);<br />

� refrigerating appliances (Category 2);<br />

� IT and telecommunications equipment and consumer equipment (Category 3);<br />

� gas discharge lights (Category 4); and<br />

� small household appliances, lighting equipment, electrical and electronic<br />

tools, toys, leisure and sports equipment, medical, monitoring and control<br />

instruments (Category 5).<br />

Local authorities can also arrange for the disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE themselves or can<br />

commission a third party to do so: By providing three months notice to the Clearing<br />

House (see Section 21.3), the local authorities may choose not to make all the WEEE<br />

in a specific group available for collection for a period <strong>of</strong> at least one year. In this case<br />

they must also ensure that treatment and recovery requirements are met.<br />

The main responsibility for the management <strong>of</strong> WEEE according to the EletkroG rests<br />

with the producers. ‘Responsibility’ covers the following issues:<br />

� Producers must take back WEEE collected from private households by public<br />

waste management authorities;<br />

459 Users <strong>of</strong> non-household WEEE - be it historical or WEEE <strong>of</strong> products sold after 13 th August 2005 -<br />

may arrange solutions for keeping waste out <strong>of</strong> disposal with producers.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


408<br />

� Producers must provide public waste management authorities with containers<br />

for WEEE to be set up at collection points and must collect the containers in a<br />

timely manner when a certain volume is reached in a WEEE group;<br />

� Organizing the transport and treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE from the public collection site<br />

to the treatment facilities;<br />

� Controlling whether old appliances can be reused;<br />

� Removal <strong>of</strong> certain substances, according to the WEEE and ROHS Directive;<br />

� Meeting recycling and recovery quotas for disposal;<br />

� Informing consumers about the possibilities and the necessity <strong>of</strong> the sound<br />

management <strong>of</strong> WEEE; and<br />

� Reporting <strong>of</strong> relevant data to the clearing house.<br />

21.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

In contrast to most other types <strong>of</strong> waste, the amount <strong>of</strong> WEEE in Germany has<br />

increased continuously over recent years. In 2006, 1.8 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> EEE was put<br />

on the market in Germany (see Table 21-1).<br />

Although collection systems for WEEE were in existence in the cities and counties<br />

prior to introduction <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG, only 10 per cent <strong>of</strong> WEEE was collected and<br />

recycled. The rest was mainly landfilled or thermally recovered in waste incinerators.<br />

Across Germany, the collection system before the introduction <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG was<br />

quite varied, with some cities collecting two types <strong>of</strong> WEEE-products and others<br />

collecting as many as 20 types, and some cities charging for the collection <strong>of</strong> WEEE,<br />

with others collecting free <strong>of</strong> charge.<br />

The timetable for the introduction and development <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG policy proceeded<br />

as follows:<br />

� 1991: Draft <strong>of</strong> a German WEEE-Ordinance (Entwurf der Elektronikschrott-<br />

Verordnung), which was updated and replaced by the ElektroG on 27 th<br />

September 1994, with producer responsibility regulated in Art. 22 <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Closed Substances and Recycling Act (Kreislaufwirtschafts- und Abfallgesetz -<br />

Krw-/AbfG);<br />

� 2003: Directive 2002/96/EC on waste electrical and electronic equipment<br />

(WEEE) and Directive 2002/95/EC 460 on the restriction <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> certain<br />

hazardous substances in electrical and electronic equipment requires that<br />

Member States comply with the Directive by 13 th August 2004;<br />

� 23 rd March 2005: ElektroG was formally adopted;<br />

460 Directive 2002/96/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 27 th January 2003 on<br />

waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE) - Joint declaration <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament, the<br />

Council and the Commission relating to Article 9, Official Journal L 037, 13.02.2003, p. 24.<br />

29/09/09


409<br />

� 31 st December 2005: Almost all regulations <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG entered into force;<br />

and<br />

� 24 th March 2006: Free <strong>of</strong> charge disposal entered into force.<br />

Table 21-1: EEE Put on the Market and Collected in Germany (2006).<br />

Product Product category<br />

category<br />

Large Household<br />

Appliances<br />

Small Household<br />

Appliances<br />

IT & Telecommunications<br />

Equipment<br />

Put Put on on on the<br />

the<br />

Market<br />

Market<br />

Weight<br />

(tonnes)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Collected Collected Amount Amount<br />

Treated Treated Amount<br />

Amount<br />

B2C B2B Total Germany Other MS<br />

Weight<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Weight<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Weight<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Weight<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Weight<br />

(tonnes)<br />

723,547 447,393 14,673 462,066 455,690 3,235<br />

144,877 41,621 1,206 42,827 36,038 6,138<br />

314,898 86,573 15,762 102,336 89,960 7,196<br />

Consumer Equipment 334,018 108,149 4,607 112,757 111,729 242<br />

Lighting Equipment 90,969 x 375 375 70 192<br />

Gas discharge lamp 25,556 5,551 x 5,551 5,401 150<br />

Electrical and Electronic<br />

Tools<br />

Toys, Sports & Leisure<br />

Equipment<br />

118,695, 10,683 899 11,582 11,001 449<br />

25.172 2.534 2.062 4.596 4.524 36<br />

Medical Products 25.711 741. 2.932 3.673 1.807 1,273<br />

Monitoring & Control<br />

Instruments<br />

18.497 948 231 1,179 869 89<br />

Automatic Dispensers 14,972 5,592 1,366 6,958 5,776 55<br />

Sum Sum<br />

1,836,913 1,836,913 709,787 709,787 44,113 44,113 753,900 753,900 753,900 734,844 734,844 19,055<br />

19,055<br />

Source: BMU, Data on WEEE in Germany in the year 2006 - BMU Explanations for the report to the EU-<br />

Commission, 5.09.2008<br />

21.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The Electrical and Electronic Equipment Act designates the responsibilities <strong>of</strong><br />

"registering", "coordinating collection" and "issuing instructions for the provision <strong>of</strong><br />

containers" to the Federal Environmental Agency (UBA) as the "Competent Authority"<br />

(central register). However, the Act provides for the Competent Authority to transfer


these responsibilities by means <strong>of</strong> designation to the Clearing House <strong>of</strong> the<br />

producers.<br />

In August 2004, the business associations ZVEI and Bitcom set up the foundation<br />

“Stiftung Elektro-Altgeräte Register- EAR” (Elektro-Altgeräte Register - WEEE register)<br />

based in Fürth/Bavaria. The EAR foundation was set up to fulfil the responsibilities <strong>of</strong><br />

the Clearing House <strong>of</strong> the producers and was made available for designation by the<br />

Federal Environmental Agency. 461<br />

The role <strong>of</strong> the EAR as a clearing house is:<br />

410<br />

� Registering producers placing EEE on the market in Germany for B2B as well<br />

as B2C equipment;<br />

� Before producers can place EEE on the market in Germany, they have to<br />

provide a guarantee, i.e. insolvency-pro<strong>of</strong> financial guarantee, independently<br />

<strong>of</strong> whether the producer complies in a group or individually, that covers the<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> sound disposal <strong>of</strong> the household appliances that the producer plans to<br />

sell after 13 th August 2005;<br />

� Based on a formula, the Clearing House determines the collection volumes for<br />

the individual producer and calculates an even temporal and regional<br />

distribution <strong>of</strong> WEEE collection quotas among all producers;<br />

� It also compiles data inter alia on equipment placed on the market, taken<br />

back and recovered equipment, and it submits the data to the Environmental<br />

Agency (Umweltbundesamt);<br />

� The supervision <strong>of</strong> the transport <strong>of</strong> WEEE from the collection site to the<br />

treatment facility.<br />

The EAR has no operational functions, like the take-back, dismantling, sorting or<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> WEEE.<br />

Once a certain amount <strong>of</strong> a category <strong>of</strong> WEEE has been collected, the municipality<br />

informs the clearing house. The clearing house decides to which <strong>of</strong> the five categories<br />

the appliance belongs, and calculates the respective volume <strong>of</strong> WEEE (including<br />

historical WEEE). The volume is important for the financing <strong>of</strong> WEEE waste<br />

management.<br />

Concerning WEEE from private households (B2C) the ElektroG states:<br />

� From 24 th March 2006, producers must finance the waste management <strong>of</strong><br />

“historical” WEEE (equipment put on the market before 13 th August 2005)<br />

calculated on the basis <strong>of</strong> the producer’s market share at the time that the<br />

WEEE management cost arises; and<br />

461 The EAR is the focal point for information concerning the management <strong>of</strong> WEEE for public<br />

authorities and the private sector and it supports decision-making. The ElektroG provides that the<br />

clearing house be constituted with a council, whose members are producers, retailers, public entities<br />

responsible for waste management, representatives at the Federal level and from the German Länder<br />

(states), and consumer and environment protection associations.<br />

29/09/09


411<br />

� Regarding “new” WEEE (equipment put on the market after 13 th August 2005),<br />

producers are only responsible for financing the collection, treatment, recovery<br />

and disposal <strong>of</strong> their own products. In this respect, the producers have to pay<br />

a financial guarantee.<br />

Concerning business equipment (B2B) the ElektroG states:<br />

� Commencing 24 th March 2006, the end-user <strong>of</strong> historical WEEE is responsible<br />

for financing the costs <strong>of</strong> management. Producers are only financially<br />

responsible for the waste management <strong>of</strong> “new” WEEE (sold after 13 th August<br />

2005).<br />

Furthermore, the clearing house has an obligation to inform the general public <strong>of</strong><br />

disposal possibilities. It is not allowed to conclude or arrange contracts with disposal<br />

enterprises.<br />

To raise the awareness <strong>of</strong> the general public, the ElektroG introduced obligations for<br />

producers, the clearing house and the competent authorities <strong>of</strong> the region (e.g.<br />

Bavaria) to inform the users <strong>of</strong> WEEE about the importance <strong>of</strong> collecting and recycling<br />

WEEE. To increase the efficiency <strong>of</strong> the treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE, the producers have a duty<br />

to inform treatment facilities about the features <strong>of</strong> their products within a year <strong>of</strong> their<br />

placement on the market.<br />

As a key instrument to measure the impact <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG, producers have the<br />

following monitoring obligations, i.e. they must collect and transfer data on the<br />

following aspects <strong>of</strong> WEEE management:<br />

1. Amount <strong>of</strong> products introduced to the market on a monthly basis;<br />

2. Annually recovered appliances by public collection site; and<br />

3. Volume <strong>of</strong> collected, recycled, reused, recovered and exported appliances.<br />

This information concerns the volume, components and materials <strong>of</strong> WEEE going into<br />

the first-treatment facility, coming out <strong>of</strong> that facility, and going to recovery facilities.<br />

The so-called ‘first-treatment site’ is obliged to provide this information to the<br />

producers. Furthermore, the first-treatment facility is subject to an annual<br />

certification. This certification will only be issued if the site proves that it can provide<br />

the data required by the producer.<br />

21.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

Prior to implementation: Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (SRU) Umweltgutachten<br />

2002, July 2002.<br />

Following implementation: Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat<br />

für Umweltfragen, SRU) Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2008, July 2008<br />

(See: http://www.umweltrat.de for further information).<br />

21.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

Prevention Prevention <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> waste waste<br />

waste<br />

Since 1 st July 2006, manufacturers <strong>of</strong> electrical and electronic equipment have been<br />

required to substitute lead, cadmium, mercury, specific chromium compounds and<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


ominated flame retardants in any new electrical and electronic equipment that they<br />

put on the market. Since the entry into force <strong>of</strong> the Electrical and Electronic<br />

Equipment Act (ElektroG), manufacturers have had to take disposal costs <strong>of</strong> products<br />

into account even in the design stage, as consumers can return old equipment to<br />

local collection points free <strong>of</strong> charge. Manufacturers and importers have to pick up<br />

waste equipment at these collection sites and take charge <strong>of</strong> subsequent<br />

management. This has brought about a reduction in the pollutant load <strong>of</strong> municipal<br />

waste. The volume <strong>of</strong> waste electrical and electronic equipment from these local<br />

collection points is about 1.8 tonnes per year. 462 Following the introduction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ElektroG, less WEEE has since been disposed <strong>of</strong> in landfills. 463<br />

However, a causal link cannot be drawn between the introduction <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG and<br />

other impacts, e.g. an improvement in the product lifetime or enhancing the<br />

recyclability <strong>of</strong> electric and electronic equipment (see lessons learned). Mr Hieronimy<br />

from Hewlett-Packard (Germany) states that for his company, the effect <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ElektroG producer responsibility system is such that it has led to no changes in their<br />

product design. Improvements in product recyclability at HP have been a result <strong>of</strong><br />

product and brand ‘image’ requirements, rather than as a result <strong>of</strong> producer<br />

responsibility. 464 Mr Hieronimy states that for him, the present implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

producer responsibility in the ElektroG does not lead to individual savings for<br />

companies due to the design <strong>of</strong> their products, but would lead to any benefits being<br />

distributed evenly among all producers. 465 This effectively implies a disincentive to<br />

change product design owing to the free-rider problem created by the shared<br />

responsibility approach.<br />

Recycling Recycling <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

Statistics for the first year <strong>of</strong> ElektroG (2006) concerning recovery, recycling and reuse<br />

<strong>of</strong> WEEE in Germany are given in Table 21-2.<br />

Statistics show that for B2C equipment, the German collection amount <strong>of</strong> 8 kg WEEE<br />

per person per year is double that <strong>of</strong> the EU collection target <strong>of</strong> 4 kg per person per<br />

year. 466<br />

Nevertheless, it remains questionable as to whether or not the main aims <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ElektroG have so far been achieved. According to Art. 1 ElektroG, the law aims to<br />

prevent waste from electrical and electronic equipment and to promote reuse,<br />

recycling and other forms <strong>of</strong> recovery to reduce both the volume <strong>of</strong> waste. The<br />

recovery and re-use <strong>of</strong> used equipment is hampered by the demolition <strong>of</strong> WEEE during<br />

collection or transport. The waste management branch claims that the demolition<br />

462 Federal Environmental Ministry, Fewer hazardous substances in electrical and electronical<br />

equipment, press statement from 30.6.2006.<br />

463 Sabine Enzinger, Bilanz ElektroG, Umweltmagazin, July-August 2007, p. 18.<br />

464 EUWID from 17 th October 2008, p.3.<br />

465 EUWID from 17 th October 2008, p.3.<br />

466 Federal Environmental Ministry (BMU), Data on EEE in Germany in the year 2006 - BMU<br />

Explanations for the report to the EU-Commission, 5.09.2008, p. 2.<br />

412<br />

29/09/09


ate <strong>of</strong> WEEE collected after the introduction <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG has increased<br />

significantly, whilst the re-use quota fell from 10 % before 24 th March 2006 to 3% in<br />

2007, resulting from the diverging duties and responsibilities for the collection and<br />

further treatment <strong>of</strong> WEEE. While the local authorities are responsible for the local<br />

collection and sorting <strong>of</strong> WEEE, producers are ultimately responsible for the re-use<br />

and recovery <strong>of</strong> WEEE. Moreover as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the ElektroG, many traditional<br />

and well-rehearsed business relationships between local authorities and waste<br />

management companies were cancelled. Instead, producers are commissioning<br />

supra-regional companies, with local companies losing their ‘influence’ on the<br />

collection and transport <strong>of</strong> WEEE. 467<br />

Table 21-2: WEEE Recovered, Recycled and Re-used in Germany 2006.<br />

413<br />

Amount<br />

Recovery<br />

Recovery<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Recovery-<br />

Quota<br />

Re Re-use Re use (components) (components) and<br />

and<br />

Recycling<br />

Recycling<br />

Amount<br />

Recycling-<br />

Quota<br />

Re Re-use Re use use <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

the<br />

whole whole appliance<br />

appliance<br />

Product Product category category Weight (tonnes) % Weight (tonnes) % Weight (tonnes)<br />

Large Household<br />

Appliances<br />

Small Household<br />

Appliances<br />

IT &<br />

Telecommunications<br />

Equipment<br />

417,507 91.0 385,725 84.0 3,141<br />

38,646 91.6 28,362 67.2 651<br />

92,602 95.3 75,562 77.8 5,179<br />

Consumer Equipment 106,225 94.9 86,900 77.6 786<br />

Lighting Equipment 262 100 231 88.2 113<br />

Gas discharge lamp 5,331 95.7 5,296 95.4 0<br />

Electrical and<br />

Electronic Tools<br />

Toys, Sports & Leisure<br />

Equipment<br />

9,615 84.0 8,000 69.9 132<br />

3,773 82.7 3,168 69.5 37<br />

Medical Products 2,929 95.1 2,524 81.9 593<br />

Monitoring & Control<br />

Instruments<br />

663 69.1 565 58.9 220<br />

Automatic Dispensers 5,506 94.4 3,731 64.0 1,126<br />

Sum Sum<br />

683,038 92.1 92.1 92.1 600,062 600,062 80.9 80.9 80.9<br />

11, 11,978 11, 978<br />

Source: BMU, Data on EEE in Germany in the year 2006 - BMU Explanations for the report to the EU-<br />

Commission, 5.09.2008<br />

467 Sabine Enzinger, Bilanz ElektroG, Umweltmagazin, July-August 2007, p. 18.


21.6 Implementation Costs<br />

Producers have to guarantee the financing <strong>of</strong> the collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> their<br />

products by participating in a collective system or by setting up an individual<br />

compliance scheme.<br />

The ZVEI (German Electrical and Electronic Manufacturers' Association) estimated<br />

that the WEEE policy would cost industry €5,000,000 per annum. In 2007, the<br />

members <strong>of</strong> the BVSE (“Bundesverband Sekundärrohst<strong>of</strong>fe und Entsorgung e.V.”)<br />

registered a cut in prices for the collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> WEEE <strong>of</strong> up to 30 %. With<br />

the second amendment <strong>of</strong> the “Ordinance on fees regarding the ElektroG” (Zweite<br />

Änderungsverordnung zur Kostenverordnung zum ElektroG) having entered into force<br />

on 1 st January 2008, the Federal Environmental Ministry has proposed a further<br />

decrease in fees <strong>of</strong> up to 40%. Nonetheless, for 2008, the Federal Environmental<br />

Ministry predicts that the overall costs <strong>of</strong> the system, as financed by fees from<br />

producers, to be approximately €5,800,000. 468 Using the total tonnes <strong>of</strong> WEEE<br />

collected in Table 21-1, the estimated cost per tonne <strong>of</strong> WEEE collected is therefore<br />

€7.69.<br />

21.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

In the “Business to Consumer” sector, producers are obliged to finance the WEEE<br />

costs associated with all products; there is no direct link to the recycling cost <strong>of</strong> the<br />

specific product that has been made by the individual producer. The shared<br />

responsibilities thus result in reduced interest by individual producers to produce<br />

products <strong>of</strong> high quality, which have a long lifetime, and which would lead to a<br />

reduction in collection and recycling costs. The picture is slightly different in the<br />

“Business-to-Business” sector, as here products have to be taken back in clearly<br />

defined ways by the producers.<br />

21.8 Complementary Policies<br />

The Electrical and Electronic Equipment Act (ElektroG) complements the general<br />

regulation on waste - the Closed Substances and Recycling Act (Kreislaufwirtschafts-<br />

und Abfallgesetz). The producer responsibility regulated in Article 22 <strong>of</strong> the Closed<br />

Substances and Recycling Act commits producers and distributors to design their<br />

products in a way that prevents waste in the manufacture and usage <strong>of</strong> a product.<br />

A further complementary policy in place is the Landfill Ordinance (Deponie-<br />

Verordnung - DeponieV); this policy still contains loopholes which weakens the landfill<br />

ban <strong>of</strong>, inter alia, the WEEE-derived shredder light fraction (SLF).<br />

468 Second Amending Ordinance on the Cost Ordinance on the Electrical and Electronic Equipment Act,<br />

in the version <strong>of</strong> 6 July 2005 (Federal Law Gazette I year 2005 p 2020), last amended by Article 1 <strong>of</strong><br />

the 2nd Ordinance Amending the Cost Ordinance on the Electrical and Electronic Equipment Act <strong>of</strong> 5<br />

December 2007 (Federal Law Gazette I year 2007 p. 2825).<br />

414<br />

29/09/09


A serious problem is the illegal export <strong>of</strong> WEEE which, according to some estimations,<br />

ranges from 10 to 15 % in Germany, and which adds pressure to recycling prices. 469<br />

Governments should ensure that the WEEE streams will reach recycling facilities<br />

operating to appropriate standards and that recycling capacities are being fully<br />

utilised. Here, the minimum and insufficient border control <strong>of</strong> WEEE exports appears<br />

to be a significant problem.<br />

21.9 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The consequences and behaviour <strong>of</strong> business and communities after two years<br />

experience with the new regulation can be summarized as follows:<br />

Following the full implementation <strong>of</strong> free <strong>of</strong> charge disposal (24 th March 2006),<br />

producers announced that they would re-finance the costs with price increases for<br />

new products. It is still unclear whether this has happened and to what extent.<br />

Gotthard Graß (General Executive Manager <strong>of</strong> the ZVEI) was reported as saying: "I<br />

expect that the prices for new appliances will increase." For some electric appliances<br />

like washing machines, recycling has probably been cost-neutral due to the high price<br />

received for scrap metal, <strong>of</strong> which there is a considerable quantity . In contrast the<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> fluorescent tubes or energy saving light bulbs is more complicated<br />

because <strong>of</strong> the mercury content. For the latter product types, the recycling revenue<br />

can amount to 20 to 60 % <strong>of</strong> the product price. Nevertheless according to Bitkom, 470<br />

the producers <strong>of</strong> PCs, computer equipment, mobile phones and entertainment<br />

electronics have only small leeway regarding price increases, due to a drop in prices<br />

in those branches resulting from competition in the EEE market, and a general<br />

decline in prices in real terms.<br />

Experts have different opinions on whether the free <strong>of</strong> charge collection system for<br />

WEEE will lead to falling or even rising waste disposal charges being levied by local<br />

authorities on householders. It is reported that some municipalities will increase<br />

waste disposal charges, arguing that they will have to enlarge and reconstruct their<br />

collection points in order to comply with the ElektroG. By contrast, the German<br />

Environmental Ministry and the Bitkom-expert Mario Tobias, are <strong>of</strong> the opinion that<br />

waste disposal charges should fall, because following the new regulations,<br />

communities no longer have to pay for the transport and recycling <strong>of</strong> the WEEE<br />

anymore, they only have to collect it. A speaker <strong>of</strong> the German Environmental Ministry<br />

is cited as saying that waste disposal charges are not very transparent anyway, as it is<br />

not known which other costs are covered as part <strong>of</strong> the charges.<br />

21.10 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The problem <strong>of</strong> free-riders is believed to be a significant one in Germany. Although all<br />

affected companies according to the ElektroG should have been registered since<br />

469 EUWID from 21 st January 2008, p.4.<br />

470 BITKOM represents 1,300 companies, some 700 <strong>of</strong> which are direct members. These include<br />

almost all <strong>of</strong> the leading players in the industry, as well as more than 500 smaller, medium-sized and<br />

new businesses, see: http://www.bitkom.org/ .<br />

415<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


November 2005, as <strong>of</strong> March 2006, only half <strong>of</strong> the companies thought to be<br />

obligated to register had done so.<br />

Regulatory <strong>of</strong>fences listed in Art. 23 ElektroG are aimed at producers placing<br />

electrical and electronic equipment on the market. Contravening the regulations <strong>of</strong><br />

the ElektroG can result in fines. Producers failing to register can be subject to a fine<br />

up to €50,000. Other <strong>of</strong>fences, like failing to collect containers, can result in a fine <strong>of</strong><br />

up to €10,000.<br />

In order to investigate violations <strong>of</strong> the regulations, an initiative <strong>of</strong> recycling<br />

companies led to the setting up <strong>of</strong> a control body called ÜWEG e.V.<br />

(Überwachungsverein zur Wahrung des ElektroG – www.ueweg.de ).<br />

Except for the EAR, the enforcement authorities <strong>of</strong> the Länder (German states) are<br />

spared the responsibility <strong>of</strong> monitoring and controlling to any large degree.<br />

21.11 Lessons Learned<br />

Key factors that determine the success <strong>of</strong> the producer responsibility for WEEE<br />

include:<br />

416<br />

� That industry designs its products for the purpose <strong>of</strong> reuse and recyclability;<br />

� That there are no free-riders. In other words, all companies need to register<br />

with the EAR;<br />

� That the collection and treatment infrastructure is tailored to the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

WEEE disposed; and<br />

� That consumers find the take-back system comfortable and are not<br />

encouraged to dispose <strong>of</strong> WEEE illegally. This is particularly a problem for<br />

small electric appliances, which may find their way into the residual waste<br />

stream.<br />

21.12 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

The essential elements that are required for this particular policy to be introduced<br />

are:<br />

1. “Willingness” <strong>of</strong> the industry to devise and implement its producer<br />

responsibility, e.g. organising the recycling system;<br />

2. Capacity to build up a recycling infrastructure, e.g. sufficient personnel in the<br />

communities for collection points, transport capacity, collection containers).<br />

3. No legal obstacles against a take-back system that is run by industry, e.g. antitrust<br />

law.<br />

29/09/09


22.0 Producer Responsibility, ELVs - Ireland<br />

22.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

An end <strong>of</strong> life vehicle (or ELV) is a car or light commercial vehicle, which is to be<br />

disposed <strong>of</strong> by the registered owner (in other words, a car or small van which is to be<br />

scrapped) as waste. Vehicles normally reach the end <strong>of</strong> their useful lives, either due<br />

to age (typically around 12-14 years), or because <strong>of</strong> heavy damage following an<br />

accident. Therefore, there is no fixed age at which a vehicle can be considered an<br />

ELV. The European Parliament and Council Directive 2000/53/EC 471 on End <strong>of</strong> Life<br />

Vehicles (known hereafter as the ‘ELV Directive’) sets out specific measures to be put<br />

in place by Member States in relation to the collection, storage, treatment,<br />

dismantling, reuse, recycling and disposal <strong>of</strong> ELVs. Under the ELV Directive, each<br />

Member State is required to:<br />

417<br />

� Achieve new recovery and recycling targets <strong>of</strong> 85% reuse/recovery by average<br />

weight per vehicle deposited for appropriate treatment by 1 January 2006 (to<br />

include 80% materials recycling), and 95% reuse/recovery by 1 January 2015<br />

(to include 85% materials recycling);<br />

� Ensure that all ELVs are dismantled, treated and recovered by industry at no<br />

extra cost to the final holder/owner <strong>of</strong> that vehicle and in a manner that does<br />

not cause environmental pollution;<br />

� Introduce new systems whereby certificates <strong>of</strong> destruction (CoD) are notified to<br />

the competent vehicle registration authorities on the deposit <strong>of</strong> ELVs by their<br />

registered owners at authorised treatment facilities (ATFs) for appropriate<br />

treatment and recovery; and<br />

� Minimise the use <strong>of</strong> specified hazardous substances in vehicles.<br />

The ELV Directive was transposed into Irish law on the 8 June 2006 through the<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006 472 (known hereafter as<br />

the ELV Regulations). The ELV Regulations place obligations on producers to establish<br />

national collection systems for the recovery and treatment <strong>of</strong> ELVs and require<br />

treatment facilities to meet specific environmental standards. A producer covers not<br />

only any vehicle manufacturer located in Ireland but extends to “any person” who<br />

imports vehicles into the state. As no vehicles are built in Ireland, it follows that the<br />

obligations for compliance with the legislation fall on vehicle importers. The producer<br />

is required to develop a network <strong>of</strong> treatment facilities that is ‘reasonably’ accessible<br />

to all and that can meet the demand associated with that producer’s ELVs. Each<br />

producer is required to develop a national collection system consisting <strong>of</strong> one ATFin<br />

every city and council area where the population <strong>of</strong> the functional area is less than or<br />

471 European Parliament and Council Directive 2000/53/EC on End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles.<br />

472 S.I. No. 282 <strong>of</strong> 2006, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


equal to 150,000 with one supplemental facility provided for each additional<br />

150,000 persons. The producer is obliged to establish a formal relationship with<br />

ATFs, but an agreement must not last longer than 3 years. This is a producer<br />

responsibility initiative based on the Polluter Pays Principle. Producers were required<br />

to register with each local authority by the 21 July 2006. They are required to apply<br />

for renewal <strong>of</strong> registration on 31 January each year.<br />

Since 1 st January 2007, owners <strong>of</strong> intact end <strong>of</strong> life cars and vans must deposit such<br />

vehicles at an ATF. When an ELV is deposited at an ATF, the owner will receive a CoD.<br />

If an ELV is deposited at an unauthorised facility, the owner will not receive a CoD and<br />

may remain recorded as the registered owner <strong>of</strong> the vehicle on the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

Transport’s National Vehicle and Driver File.<br />

ATFs provide a free take-back service for vehicles <strong>of</strong> that producer’s brand. An ATF<br />

that forms part <strong>of</strong> a producer’s network is bound to accept any specified vehicle <strong>of</strong><br />

that producer’s brand. If essential parts <strong>of</strong> the vehicle (for example, engine, gearbox,<br />

transmission and catalytic converter) are missing, or the vehicle contains waste, then<br />

a charge may apply. An operator <strong>of</strong> an ATF is obliged to:<br />

418<br />

� Issue the registered owner with a CoD;<br />

� Ensure the facility is operated under an appropriate waste licence or permit;<br />

� Meet the minimum technical requirements for the storage, treatment and<br />

recovery <strong>of</strong> ELVs and the storage <strong>of</strong> components containing fluids, spare parts<br />

etc.;<br />

� Keep records <strong>of</strong> end <strong>of</strong> life vehicle materials for reuse, recycling, recovery and<br />

disposal and report these records to local authorities annually;<br />

� Use component and material coding to facilitate identification <strong>of</strong> components<br />

that are suitable for reuse and recovery;<br />

� Forward the details <strong>of</strong> the CoDto the National Vehicle and Driver File, maintained<br />

by the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Transport; and<br />

� The vehicle must be treated within 10 days <strong>of</strong> being deposited at the facility.<br />

The ELV Regulations also impose obligations on producers to reduce hazardous<br />

waste produced from cars. About 25% <strong>of</strong> a vehicle’s weight is classified as hazardous<br />

waste, therefore vehicles account for almost 10% <strong>of</strong> the total amount <strong>of</strong> hazardous<br />

waste generated annually in the European Union. 473 Hazardous materials include<br />

lead acid batteries, fluids including lubricating oil, coolant, brake fluid and catalytic<br />

converters, all <strong>of</strong> which must be disposed <strong>of</strong> safely in order to prevent pollution. The<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> ELVs at dedicated treatment centres, designed to dismantle vehicles in<br />

accordance with environmental best practice, allows hazardous substances to be<br />

removed and segregated from the main vehicle metal mass. Thus there is a welcome<br />

reduction in the volumes <strong>of</strong> hazardous waste that would have been previously<br />

generated by the shredding <strong>of</strong> whole vehicles without any pre-treatment. Such a<br />

473 Directive 2000/53/EC on end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles, (Version 1 – January 2005) – Guidance Document.<br />

29/09/09


practice previously resulted in the contamination <strong>of</strong> non-hazardous components with<br />

hazardous components, leading to the generation <strong>of</strong> greater overall volumes <strong>of</strong><br />

hazardous waste. Producers are required to ensure that materials and components <strong>of</strong><br />

specified vehicles do not contain lead, mercury, cadmium or hexavalent chromium<br />

other than in specified cases. Producers must maintain appropriate documentation<br />

for a period <strong>of</strong> seven years to verify that materials and components <strong>of</strong> vehicles are in<br />

compliance with the provisions <strong>of</strong> the ELV Regulations.<br />

It is estimated that in some EU member states, up to 7% <strong>of</strong> all ELVs are illegally<br />

dumped. 474 The ELV Regulations do not encourage random dismantling <strong>of</strong> ELVs, as<br />

ATFs impose a charge on the vehicle owner if essential parts <strong>of</strong> the vehicle are<br />

removed prior to delivery. This economic consequence should have the desired effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> preventing the generation <strong>of</strong> waste in the form <strong>of</strong> unsightly redundant vehicles<br />

(prior to the introduction <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> life Vehicles) Regulations<br />

2006).<br />

22.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The ELV Regulations were introduced to control the disposal <strong>of</strong> vehicles, which have<br />

reached the end <strong>of</strong> their life due to damage or age, because they can pose a threat to<br />

the environment due to the hazardous materials contained in them. In addition the<br />

Regulations are intended to improve the environmental performance <strong>of</strong> vehicle<br />

dismantling activities and promote additional recycling in this sector.<br />

The ELV Directive sets out objectives relating to the prevention, collection, treatment,<br />

reuse and recovery <strong>of</strong> ELVs. Article 4 <strong>of</strong> the Directive sets out objectives in relation to<br />

prevention and encourages limiting the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances to prevent their<br />

release into the environment, making recycling easier and avoiding the need to<br />

dispose <strong>of</strong> hazardous waste. Article 8 sets out objectives on ensuring that producers<br />

provide information on coding standards and dismantling information for new<br />

vehicles.<br />

The ELV Regulations encourage the development and optimisation <strong>of</strong> ways to reuse,<br />

recycle and recover ELVs and their components. The Regulations encourage the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> markets for recycled materials integrating an increase in the quantity<br />

<strong>of</strong> recycled materials used in vehicles and other products. Product reuse is<br />

encompassed in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development<br />

(OECD) definition <strong>of</strong> waste prevention.<br />

22.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

Following a period <strong>of</strong> public consultation, the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> life Vehicle)<br />

Regulations 2006 (S.I. No. 282 <strong>of</strong> 2006) were introduced in Ireland by the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government (DoEHLG) and came<br />

into effect on 8 June 2006. The Regulations fully transpose the provisions <strong>of</strong> the ELV<br />

Directive and are intended to facilitate its implementation in Ireland. The Regulations<br />

474 Commission Proposal COM (97) 358 Final COD 970194 Official Journal C 337, 07.11.1997<br />

Commission <strong>of</strong> the European Communities.<br />

419<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


accompany Part VA <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act 1996 on End <strong>of</strong> life Vehicles<br />

(inserted by Section 44 <strong>of</strong> the Protection <strong>of</strong> the Environment Act 2003).<br />

22.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The key organisations involved in implementation and management <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> life Vehicles) Regulations 2006 are the following:<br />

420<br />

� Local Authorities;<br />

� EPA;<br />

� Producers;<br />

� ATFs;<br />

� Vehicle Owners; and<br />

� Main Stakeholders:<br />

29/09/09<br />

• Irish Motor Vehicle Recyclers Association (IMVRA);<br />

• Metal Recyclers Association <strong>of</strong> Ireland (MRAI); and<br />

• Society <strong>of</strong> the Irish Motor Industry (SIMI).<br />

� National Vehicle and Driver File; and<br />

� The Scrap Industry.<br />

Local Local Autho Authorities Autho Authorities<br />

rities<br />

Under the Regulations, local authorities are responsible for ensuring the effective<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the system including the enforcement <strong>of</strong> all relevant provisions<br />

relating to the permitting <strong>of</strong> ATFs, approval <strong>of</strong> national collection plans for their area,<br />

receipt <strong>of</strong> reporting data and where appropriate, producer responsibility provisions<br />

concerning the administration <strong>of</strong> the system <strong>of</strong> producer registration within their<br />

functional area.<br />

EPA<br />

EPA<br />

The EPA have a peripheral role in the collation <strong>of</strong> data and preparation <strong>of</strong> statistical<br />

reports under the ELV Directive and Regulations.<br />

Producers<br />

Producers<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> life Vehicles) Regulations 2006 place obligations on<br />

producers (vehicle manufacturers and pr<strong>of</strong>essional importers) to carry out the<br />

following:<br />

� Establish national collection systems for the recovery and treatment <strong>of</strong> ELVs.<br />

From 1 January 2007 owners <strong>of</strong> intact end <strong>of</strong> life cars and vans can deposit<br />

them free <strong>of</strong> charge at ATFs. An exception to the free take-back principle is<br />

provided where a vehicle is missing its essential components or where waste<br />

has been added to the vehicle.<br />

� Each producer's national collection system is required to have at least one ATF<br />

in every city and county council area that will provide free take back for vehicles


421<br />

<strong>of</strong> that producer's brand or for which that producer has responsibility. Producers<br />

are required to have additional ATFs in place in those counties and cities with a<br />

larger population base (i.e. one additional facility for each additional 150,000<br />

persons in the relevant county or city);<br />

� Each producer is required to register with each local authority identifying the<br />

level <strong>of</strong> ELVs they anticipate being responsible for and the ATFs they plan to<br />

make use <strong>of</strong> in that area;<br />

� To ensure that the materials and components <strong>of</strong> specified vehicles do not<br />

contain lead, mercury, cadmium or hexavalent chromium other than in cases<br />

specified in the Fourth Schedule <strong>of</strong> the Regulations and that technical<br />

documentation must be made available by the producer to verify compliance<br />

with these requirements;<br />

� To compile and maintain appropriate documentation, for a period <strong>of</strong> seven<br />

years, to verify that the materials and components <strong>of</strong> vehicles are in compliance<br />

with the provisions <strong>of</strong> the Regulations. Each year they must submit an annual<br />

report to the local authority on the treatment <strong>of</strong> ELVs, including steps taken to<br />

encourage recycling and reuse;<br />

� Each producer, in liaison with vehicle material and equipment manufacturers,<br />

use component and material coding standards to facilitate the identification <strong>of</strong><br />

those components and materials which are suitable for reuse and recovery; and<br />

� Producers are also obliged to make available to ATFs dismantling information for<br />

each type <strong>of</strong> new specified vehicle put on the market in Ireland within six<br />

months <strong>of</strong> these vehicles being put on the market in Ireland.<br />

Authorised Authorised Treatment Treatment Facilities<br />

Facilities<br />

ATFs must operate under a waste licence or as appropriate a waste permit and meet<br />

the minimum technical requirements for the following:<br />

� Storage (including temporary storage) <strong>of</strong> ELVs prior to their being the subject <strong>of</strong><br />

appropriate treatment and recovery;<br />

� Appropriate treatment and recovery <strong>of</strong> ELVs; and<br />

� Storage <strong>of</strong> components containing fluids, recoverable components and spare<br />

parts.<br />

ATFs must keep records <strong>of</strong> the aggregate weight <strong>of</strong> materials for reuse, recycling,<br />

recovery and disposal arising from ELVs and report to local authorities on an annual<br />

basis.<br />

From the 1st January 2007 and onwards, on the deposit <strong>of</strong> an ELV at an ATF for<br />

appropriate treatment and recovery, the owner or operator <strong>of</strong> that facility must:<br />

� Issue a CoDto the registered owner, an authorised person <strong>of</strong> a local authority or<br />

a member <strong>of</strong> An Garda Síochána; and<br />

� Allow all relevant information relating to that CoDto be noted on the National<br />

Vehicle and Driver File;<br />

No charge may be imposed by the ATF on the registered owner <strong>of</strong> the ELV in respect<br />

<strong>of</strong> the CoD.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Vehicle Vehicle Vehicle Owners Owners<br />

Owners<br />

An obligation is also imposed on vehicle owners, where the registered owner <strong>of</strong> a<br />

specified vehicle intends to discard that vehicle as waste; he or she is required to<br />

deposit that vehicle at an ATF.<br />

Main Main Stakeholders<br />

Stakeholders<br />

Stakeholders<br />

422<br />

� Irish Motor Vehicle Recyclers Association (IMVRA),<br />

� Metal Recyclers Association <strong>of</strong> Ireland (MRAI), and<br />

� Society <strong>of</strong> the Irish Motor Industry (SIMI).<br />

These stakeholders were actively engaged with the DoEHLG in regard to the effective<br />

transposition and implementation <strong>of</strong> the ELV Directive.<br />

National National Vehicle Vehicle and and Driver Driver File<br />

File<br />

The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Transport’s National Vehicle and Driver File maintains records <strong>of</strong><br />

registered owners <strong>of</strong> vehicles. All information relating to CoDare forwarded to the<br />

National Vehicle and Driver File.<br />

The The Scrap Scrap Industry<br />

Industry<br />

The scrap industry, divided in simple terms between the dismantlers, who<br />

disassemble the car for parts, and the shredders, who crush the remaining hulk, and<br />

are required to implement higher reuse rates and stricter anti-pollution stipulations to<br />

ensure further materials recycling <strong>of</strong> ELVs.<br />

22.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

The EPA is responsible for collecting data through the National <strong>Waste</strong> Report project.<br />

The Core Prevention Team <strong>of</strong> the EPA engages with the different sector players to<br />

ascertain how waste management data for ELVs might be best compiled. The EPA<br />

are currently conducting shredder trials to assess the material content <strong>of</strong> ELVs<br />

recovered in Ireland. This information is due to be published later this year.<br />

There are obligations on all ATFs to keep records <strong>of</strong> the aggregate weight <strong>of</strong> materials<br />

for reuse, recycling, recovery and disposal arising from ELVs and report to local<br />

authorities on an annual basis.<br />

Given that the Regulations were only implemented relatively recently in Ireland<br />

reliable statistics cannot be identified on current recycling levels. 475 Reliable reporting<br />

systems have to be put in place to allow firm conclusions to be drawn as to the<br />

percentages <strong>of</strong> material that are being reused or recovered in some way. Delays are<br />

also being experience in assembling definitive data.<br />

With the arrival <strong>of</strong> the ELV Directive, it became important for information on the<br />

arisings and management <strong>of</strong> ELVs in Ireland to be made available, in order that<br />

475 European Parliament 2007: End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive - An Assessment <strong>of</strong> the Current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> Implementation by Member States.<br />

29/09/09


Ireland would be able to meet the requirements <strong>of</strong> the Directive in the best manner<br />

possible. In the absence <strong>of</strong> a system <strong>of</strong> de-registration, several methods <strong>of</strong> estimation<br />

were used in an EPA study carried out in 2002. 476 These studies consisted <strong>of</strong> both<br />

direct and indirect methods. The direct methods involved surveying metal recovery<br />

operators and the single metal recycler in Ireland, which was in operation until June<br />

2001. The indirect methods consisted <strong>of</strong> using formulae developed by the European<br />

Topic Centre on <strong>Waste</strong>. Statistics provided by the DoEHLGs Vehicle Registration Unit<br />

were also used. Two methods were considered to provide the most accurate<br />

estimates. The survey <strong>of</strong> the metal shredding facilities provided an estimate <strong>of</strong><br />

176,632 ELVs in 2000. The adjusted ETC/W method provided an estimate <strong>of</strong><br />

217,203 ELVs in 2000.<br />

22.5.1 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

In the absence <strong>of</strong> any existing published information on ELVs in Ireland, the EPA<br />

carried out a study in 2002 (as outlined above) highlights the situation at the time<br />

with regard to the arisings and management <strong>of</strong> ELVs in Ireland. 477<br />

A Statement on Regulatory Impact <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles)<br />

Regulations 2006 was published by the DoEHLG in May 2006. 478 This document<br />

assessed the likely impacts, effects and costs associated with implementation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ELV Directive.<br />

The European Parliament issued a report in 2007 assessing the current state <strong>of</strong><br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the ELV Directive by Member States. 479 This document suggests<br />

that it is too early to draw definitive conclusions as to whether targets for recycling<br />

and recovery have been widely met or not.<br />

A paper was circulated by Duncan Laurence Environmental in February 2007. This<br />

paper provides a legislation summary <strong>of</strong> the ELV Regulations. 480<br />

22.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

The uncontrolled disposal <strong>of</strong> end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles can pose a serious threat to the<br />

environment due to the materials contained in them and the method in which they<br />

are managed. The overriding aim <strong>of</strong> the Regulations is to protect the environment and<br />

human health.<br />

476 EPA (2002) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles – A Sectoral Report.<br />

477 EPA (2002) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles – A Sectoral Report<br />

478 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage & Local Government (May 2006) Statement on<br />

Regulatory Impact – <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006.<br />

479 European Parliament 2007: End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive - An Assessment <strong>of</strong> the Current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> Implementation by Member States.<br />

480 Duncan Laurence Environmental (February 2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

Regulations 2006, Legislation Summary.<br />

423<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Arising from the free take back <strong>of</strong> end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles, qualitative environmental<br />

benefits arguably grow in society, by reducing the numbers <strong>of</strong> vehicles being<br />

abandoned in public places and by increasing awareness amongst the general public<br />

in relation to the proper treatment and disposal <strong>of</strong> end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles. The system<br />

whereby authorised treatment facilities (ATFs) will issue Certificates <strong>of</strong> Destruction<br />

(CoDs) will contribute to the improvement <strong>of</strong> Ireland’s vehicle registration system and<br />

may also help combat certain forms <strong>of</strong> anti-social behaviour associated with end-<strong>of</strong>life<br />

vehicles.<br />

Storage and treatment standards will be improved in line with the requirements <strong>of</strong><br />

Annex 1 <strong>of</strong> the ELV Directive. These new standards will reduce the risk <strong>of</strong> negative<br />

environmental impacts on both the environment and human health.<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006 transpose the aim <strong>of</strong><br />

the Directive on prevention <strong>of</strong> waste arisings from end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles and promoting<br />

the collection, re-use and recycling <strong>of</strong> their components. Vehicles are to be treated in<br />

an environmentally sound manner resulting in higher environmental standards across<br />

all facilities involved in the collection, storage and treatment <strong>of</strong> end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles.<br />

22.6.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

The Regulations promote the prevention <strong>of</strong> waste through specific provisions such as<br />

restrictions on the use <strong>of</strong> specified hazardous substances in the manufacture <strong>of</strong> new<br />

vehicles. While motor manufacturing does not take place in Ireland, the Regulations<br />

transpose the provisions in the Directive on the restriction <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances<br />

in motor vehicles and the Irish environment will benefit from this restriction on the<br />

future use <strong>of</strong> these substances 481 . Restricting and reducing the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous<br />

substances prevents their release into the environment, thereby avoiding the need to<br />

dispose <strong>of</strong> future hazardous waste arisings and further facilitating the recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

specified vehicles at end <strong>of</strong> life.<br />

The Regulations place eco-design obligations on vehicle producers introducing the<br />

prohibition <strong>of</strong> heavy metals for materials and components <strong>of</strong> specified vehicles.<br />

Vehicles that a producer places on the market cannot contain lead, mercury,<br />

cadmium or hexavalent chromium other than in the cases specified in the Fourth<br />

Schedule <strong>of</strong> the 2006 Regulations. These restrictions thereby encourage the motor<br />

manufacturing industry to design and produce more reusable and recyclable<br />

parts/components and hence adopting more environmentally friendly practices in the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> materials.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> prevention is defined as the eliminating and reduction at source <strong>of</strong> material in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> waste arisings and harmful substances. By virtue <strong>of</strong> the above, the End <strong>of</strong><br />

Life Vehicles Regulations result in hazardous waste prevention and minimisation.<br />

481 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage & Local Government (May 2006) Statement on<br />

Regulatory Impact – <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006.<br />

424<br />

29/09/09


22.6.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

The Regulations introduce new environmental standards to ensure that as much<br />

material as possible is re-used, recovered and in particular recycled from an ELV and<br />

that this process is carried out in a way that does not harm the environment. Under<br />

the Regulations, producers and ATFs are required to meet new recovery and recycling<br />

targets for ELVs <strong>of</strong>:<br />

425<br />

� 85% reuse / recovery by average weight per vehicle deposited for appropriate<br />

treatment by 1 st January 2006 (to include 80% materials recycling); and<br />

� 95% reuse / recovery by 1 st January 2015 (to include 85% materials recycling).<br />

The Regulations identify treatment operations for the depollution <strong>of</strong> ELVs and further<br />

affirm that the removal <strong>of</strong> any article or material from a vehicle, shall be carried out in<br />

such manner so as to best promote it’s recycling. The provisions relating to designing<br />

for recycling in Part IV <strong>of</strong> the Regulations will encourage the motor manufacturing<br />

industry to produce more recyclable parts, design for reuse and adopt more<br />

environmental friendly practices in the use <strong>of</strong> materials. The ambitious reuse,<br />

recovery and recycling targets that Ireland is now required to achieve in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

ELVs, will have a consequential result in that significant volumes <strong>of</strong> automotive<br />

shredder residues (ASR) will be diverted from landfill. The Directive will facilitate the<br />

environmental management <strong>of</strong> 100,000 ELVs which arise annually in Ireland. 482<br />

22.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The introduction <strong>of</strong> the ELV Directive in Ireland has cost implications for both industry<br />

and State bodies involved, in particular local authorities.<br />

Local authorities will have responsibility under the Regulations for administering and<br />

enforcing the scheme in their functional areas. This will impose significant costs. As<br />

this is a producer responsibility initiative based on the polluter pays principle, the<br />

Regulations provide for a fee-based registration system which will go towards meeting<br />

local authority costs in administering and enforcing the Regulations in their functional<br />

areas. In making an application for registration to each local authority, producers<br />

must pay the following registration fees to each local authority:<br />

� €1,000 for producers whose annual turnover was less than or equal to<br />

€50,000,000;<br />

� €2,500 in respect <strong>of</strong> producers whose annual turnover was greater than<br />

€50,000,000 but less than or equal to €100,000,000; and<br />

� €6,000 in respect <strong>of</strong> producers whose annual turnover was greater than<br />

€100,000,000.<br />

The registration fee system will have cost implications for industry estimated at<br />

€3.4m on an annual basis, but will result in cost recovery for local authorities for<br />

482 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage & Local Government (May 2006) Statement on<br />

Regulatory Impact – <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


expenditure incurred in implementing and enforcing the Regulations for this producer<br />

responsibility based scheme. These fees are based on estimates provided by local<br />

authorities. Article 11(7) <strong>of</strong> the Regulations allow the Minister to review the fees after<br />

the 1 st October 2007 and empowers the Minister to adjust the fees set upwards or<br />

downwards.<br />

The Regulations impose administrative responsibilities on producers in terms <strong>of</strong> the<br />

preparation and submission <strong>of</strong> implementation plans to local authorities and data<br />

compilation and reporting, the latter also applying to ATFs who in addition will incur<br />

some costs in managing the system <strong>of</strong> CoDs. Permitted facilities have to report data<br />

to local authorities and the extra administrative burden on ATFs should not give rise<br />

to significant costs.<br />

While there is no accurate information available on the establishment and upgrading<br />

<strong>of</strong> ATFs, the initial investment in Ireland to ensure a national network <strong>of</strong> 43<br />

contracted ATF’s to the standards required by the Regulations could cost in the range<br />

<strong>of</strong> €1.7m. 483 The National Hazardous <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan 2008-2012 states<br />

that approximately 82 ATFs were confirmed to be in operation in Ireland. This plan<br />

suggests the need for the number <strong>of</strong> ATFs to increase in order to ensure that all ELVs<br />

are managed according to the Regulations and EU Directive.<br />

22.8 Response from Public and Industry<br />

We are not aware <strong>of</strong> any document, which highlights these. 484<br />

The vehicle manufacturers business strategy is based around selling new vehicles<br />

and supplying new parts for these vehicles. The ELV Regulations state that all<br />

information required for the appropriate treatment and recovery <strong>of</strong> end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles<br />

shall be made available to authorised treatment facilities by vehicle producers and<br />

vehicle component manufacturers. This effectively allows for the availability <strong>of</strong><br />

pr<strong>of</strong>essional and technical information to the car dismantling industry.<br />

22.9 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The EU Directive on ELVs aims to improve the environmental performance <strong>of</strong> all<br />

economic operators involved in the life cycle <strong>of</strong> vehicles. Bearing in mind that cars,<br />

vans, etc. driven on Irish roads are manufactured outside <strong>of</strong> Ireland, it is decided to<br />

consider technical change and innovation on an international context.<br />

The impact <strong>of</strong> economic instruments, induced by the EU Directive on end <strong>of</strong> life<br />

vehicles, on innovation paths in car manufacturing is addressed in a paper produced<br />

by Massimiliani Mazzanti and Roberto Zoboli (University <strong>of</strong> Ferrara). 485<br />

483 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage & Local Governement (May 2006) Statement on<br />

Regulatory Impact – <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006.<br />

484 The EPA were contacted in relation to responses from public and industry.<br />

485 Massimiliano Mazzanti and Roberto Zoboli (May 2005) Economic Instruments and Induced<br />

Innovation: The Case <strong>of</strong> End <strong>of</strong> life Vehicles European Policies, University <strong>of</strong> Ferrara, Italy.<br />

426<br />

29/09/09


According to this paper:<br />

427<br />

� The creation <strong>of</strong> networks <strong>of</strong> dismantlers linked to individual car companies has<br />

been a major organisational innovation given the previously existing limited<br />

relationships between the car industry and post-consumer ELV treatments.<br />

However, contractual arrangements between the main actors (carmakers,<br />

dismantlers, shredders, and recyclers) differ from country to country.<br />

� Innovative developments concerning design for dismantling (DFD) are taking<br />

place in all car companies. DFD may consist <strong>of</strong> small changes in the partassembling<br />

systems or it may imply changes and adaptations <strong>of</strong> components<br />

and parts. The boundaries between DFD and design for recycling (DFR) are not<br />

clear-cut.<br />

� DFR requires definition and measure <strong>of</strong> “recyclability”. European carmakers<br />

work on the development <strong>of</strong> “recyclability coefficients” for materials and<br />

components and include lists <strong>of</strong> not admitted or undesired<br />

substances/materials in the technical specifications imposed to component<br />

suppliers. Thus, a “responsibility transfer” between industries takes place. DFR<br />

is also increasingly linked to Life-Cycle Analysis (LCA). Most carmakers are<br />

investing in recycling-oriented LCA at the research & development (R&D) level<br />

and, in some cases, they are transferring results to practice. LCA is generally still<br />

limited to specific materials or car components. DFR pushes most carmakers to<br />

pursue a simplification <strong>of</strong> the material regime. “Easily” (i.e. economically)<br />

recyclable materials are favoured and, as a consequence, the trend towards the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> certain polymers and composite materials is weakening. There is a<br />

propensity to reduce the number <strong>of</strong> polymers in favour <strong>of</strong> those having the best<br />

recycling possibilities and a process <strong>of</strong> inter-polymer substitution is underway.<br />

The legislation not only transposed into Irish law the EU Directive on End <strong>of</strong> Life<br />

Vehicles (Directive 2000/53), it also made a significant amendment to the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Permit) Regulations 1998. This amendment enlarged the decisionmaking<br />

criteria under which all types <strong>of</strong> waste permit application received since 8<br />

June 2006 are considered 486 .<br />

22.10 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The Regulations are designed to allow competition to operate effectively and should<br />

not lead to market distortions, particularly in relation to existing small businesses<br />

operating in the scrap-vehicle dismantling sector.<br />

Each producer is required to establish a national system for the collection and<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> negative value ELVs for which they are responsible. While the national<br />

network, which a producer puts in place for the collection and treatment <strong>of</strong> ELVs,<br />

must be a minimum <strong>of</strong> 43 ATFs nationally, there is no maximum limit; hence there will<br />

be opportunities for the existing operators to compete for this business.<br />

486 Duncan Laurence Environmental (February 2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

Regulations 2006, Legislation Summary.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Anti-competitive practices are addressed by the inclusion in the Regulations <strong>of</strong> a<br />

maximum period <strong>of</strong> three years for any agreements made between producers and<br />

ATFs. The requirement to meet common minimum treatment standards will also<br />

encourage a level playing field and facilitate the market to operate efficiently 487.<br />

It is suggested that the system whereby ATFs issue CoDs contributes to the<br />

improvement <strong>of</strong> Ireland’s vehicle registration system and can also help combat<br />

certain forms <strong>of</strong> anti-social behaviour associated with ELVs. 488<br />

22.11 Complementary Policies<br />

Both the End <strong>of</strong> life Vehicle Regulations and the Batteries Regulations 489 contain<br />

substance restrictions. The substance restrictions in Part I <strong>of</strong> the Batteries<br />

Regulations (for the use <strong>of</strong> mercury and cadmium) indicate that these apply without<br />

prejudice to the ELV Regulations, which means that the prohibitions contained in Part<br />

II <strong>of</strong> the Batteries Regulations do not apply to batteries covered by the ELV<br />

Regulations. 490<br />

The ELV Regulations restrict the use <strong>of</strong> mercury, cadmium and lead in cars. However<br />

it allows a maximum concentration <strong>of</strong> mercury <strong>of</strong> up to 0.1% by weight and per<br />

homogenous material. There is an exemption for the use <strong>of</strong> cadmium in batteries for<br />

electric vehicles, which expires on the 31 December 2008, and an exemption for lead<br />

in batteries without expiry date.<br />

Both the ELV and the Batteries Regulations establish the principle <strong>of</strong> producer<br />

responsibility. A car producer is also regarded as a battery producer in a Member<br />

State under the Batteries Regulations if it places the battery on the market (inside the<br />

car) for the first time in that Member State on a pr<strong>of</strong>essional basis. This is to ensure<br />

that there is a producer responsible for all batteries placed on the market. However,<br />

the Batteries Regulations states that Member States should avoid any double<br />

charging <strong>of</strong> producers when car batteries are collected under the ELV Regulations.<br />

The focus <strong>of</strong> the RoHS (Restriction <strong>of</strong> Hazardous Substances) Regulations 491 is to<br />

limit the amount <strong>of</strong> hazardous metals contained in electrical and electronic<br />

components. The list includes lead, mercury, hexavalent chromium, cadmium and<br />

certain organic compounds. In a similar manner, the ELV Regulations is primarily<br />

targeted toward hexavalent chromium content in automotive components. The goal <strong>of</strong><br />

487 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage & Local Government (May 2006) Statement on<br />

Regulatory Impact – <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006.<br />

488 Ibid.<br />

489 <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Batteries and Accumulators) Regulations 2008 (S.I No. 268 <strong>of</strong> 2008)<br />

490 Commision Services Document (April 2008) Questions and Answers on the Batteries Directive<br />

(2006/66/EC)<br />

491 <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Restriction Of Certain Hazardous Substances in Electrical and Electronic<br />

Equipment)(Amendment) Regulations 2008 (SI 376 <strong>of</strong> 2008)<br />

428<br />

29/09/09


oth pieces <strong>of</strong> legislation is to restrict, or eliminate, the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials in<br />

manufactured goods sold overseas.<br />

22.12 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

It is difficult to determine the actual costs for the treatment <strong>of</strong> ELVs, however, it has<br />

been estimated to be in the region <strong>of</strong> €60 to €80/vehicle. These costs could accrue<br />

to circa €6.6m annually.<br />

KPMG carried out two studies with a view to determining the appropriate levy to be<br />

paid to authorised treatment facilities for the depollution <strong>of</strong> ELVs. 492 The first report in<br />

May 2002 recommended that a levy be set at €153/ELV excluding VAT; in a<br />

subsequent report completed in 2003 KPMG recommended a revised figure <strong>of</strong><br />

€120/ELV excluding VAT. These figures included the costs <strong>of</strong> depollution. The reports<br />

were based on an analysis <strong>of</strong> the costs and revenues associated with dismantling an<br />

end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicle, taking account <strong>of</strong> the labour / administration costs. The reports<br />

noted the volatile nature <strong>of</strong> the market for hulks and scrap metal and the<br />

susceptibility <strong>of</strong> this market to price fluctuations. The second KPMG report noted that<br />

there was scope for the price <strong>of</strong> any proposed levy to fall to €60 to €70 per vehicle.<br />

It is reasonable to suggest the manufacturing cost <strong>of</strong> vehicles has been affected by<br />

the specific requirements imposed on vehicle manufacturers. The reduction <strong>of</strong><br />

hazardous components, the labelling <strong>of</strong> components for recycling, design for<br />

dismantling has, most likely, imposed upward pressure on vehicle manufacturing<br />

costs. However, as technologies develop the cost <strong>of</strong> such change may diminish. As a<br />

result <strong>of</strong> the competitive nature <strong>of</strong> vehicle sales and the numerous variables involved,<br />

it is difficult to determine if additional costs have been passed on to the end<br />

user/customer.<br />

22.13 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

It is an <strong>of</strong>fence for an individual or an ATF to fail to comply with the law on the<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> ELVs. In particular, it is an <strong>of</strong>fence not to obey the rules concerning vehicle<br />

CoD, or not to deposit at an ATF a vehicle intended to discard as waste.<br />

Penalties for <strong>of</strong>fences set out under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Acts apply. On summary<br />

conviction a fine <strong>of</strong> up to €3,000 and/or 12 months imprisonment can be imposed.<br />

For conviction on indictment a fine <strong>of</strong> up to €15,000,000 and/or 10 years<br />

imprisonment is available to the court.<br />

492 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage & Local Government (May 2006) Statement on<br />

Regulatory Impact – <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles) Regulations 2006.<br />

429<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


22.14 Lessons Learned<br />

22.14.1 General Lessons<br />

The National Hazardous <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan 2008-2012 493 states that<br />

approximately 82 ATFs were confirmed to be in operation in Ireland. Two companies<br />

(Hammond Lane Metal Company and Hegarty Metal Recycling) operate three vehicle<br />

shredders in the Republic <strong>of</strong> Ireland. The National Hazardous <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Plan 2008-2012, suggests the need for the number <strong>of</strong> ATFs to increase in order to<br />

ensure that all ELVs are managed according to the Regulations.<br />

Part IV to the ELV Regulations sets out design requirements in respect <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

prevention and the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances in new motor vehicles. Obligations<br />

for compliance with these provision rests not only on vehicle manufactures, they<br />

apply also to vehicle importers located in Ireland. Manufacturers and vehicle<br />

importers are also charged with the requirement to inform “the competent authority<br />

prescribed by the Minister for this purpose” <strong>of</strong> non-complaint vehicles in instances<br />

where vehicle components contain hazardous substances above specified thresholds.<br />

These provisions came into effect immediately on the 8th June 2006, despite the fact<br />

that no enforcement body has been prescribed at the time <strong>of</strong> writing. 494<br />

The absence <strong>of</strong> data on performance thus far suggests that data reporting is not as<br />

good as might have been expected.<br />

493 EPA (2008) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme, Prevention Plan 2009 – 2012, Wexford: EPA.<br />

494 Duncan Laurence Environmental (February 2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles Regs<br />

2006, Legislation Summary.<br />

430<br />

29/09/09


23.0 Producer Responsibility, ELVs - <strong>International</strong><br />

23.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicle (ELV) policies have the general aim to reduce the environmental<br />

impacts associated with vehicles that have come to the end <strong>of</strong> their life, through<br />

mechanical failures, accident or other economic factors. They explicitly aim to<br />

increase the quantity <strong>of</strong> vehicles legally scrapped, increase the recovery rates <strong>of</strong><br />

materials from those vehicles, reduce the impact <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials by enforcing<br />

depollution standards at authorised treatment facilities (ATF), and promote innovation<br />

in vehicle design in order to make components eminently more recyclable.<br />

In essence, the structures <strong>of</strong> the policies are based on producer responsibility; hence<br />

the vehicle manufacturers finance the cost <strong>of</strong> treatment net <strong>of</strong> revenue from the sale<br />

<strong>of</strong> recycled materials. However, the costs <strong>of</strong> some systems are financed directly by<br />

levies imposed on the consumer at the point <strong>of</strong> sale <strong>of</strong> all new vehicles.<br />

The main driver behind the policy in the EU, for example, was the level <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

generated from ELVs and disposed <strong>of</strong> in landfill, and the need to reduce the<br />

associated environmental impacts. Alternatively, in countries like Japan and Korea,<br />

the policy has been developed to both implement ideals <strong>of</strong> ‘shared responsibility’ but<br />

also to ensure that cars produced in those countries maintain international approval<br />

by complying with the tough standards set out in the EU ELV Directive. This Directive<br />

appears to be the most substantial and recognised around the globe, and one that<br />

other international policies aspire to, both in terms <strong>of</strong> purpose, and specific recovery<br />

rates.<br />

Many policies are developed so that there is zero cost to the final owner <strong>of</strong> the<br />

vehicle. Free take back <strong>of</strong> vehicles is a key element to ensuring that ELVs are not<br />

abandoned when the cost <strong>of</strong> recovery is high. This is, in part, driven by the value <strong>of</strong><br />

metals in the recycling markets. When the value <strong>of</strong> recycled metals is low the systems<br />

implemented by the policies will fund the continued operation <strong>of</strong> the ATFs that have<br />

been set up to manage the recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> ELVs. If this system was not in<br />

place and the final owner had to ‘foot the bill’ one would see a sharp increase in<br />

abandoned vehicles that would be directly related to peoples’ willingness (or<br />

unwillingness in this case) to pay for the final disposal <strong>of</strong> their vehicle.<br />

In the EU the EC has evaluated the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the EU ELV Directive and found<br />

that, notwithstanding the variation in compliance with the Directive across member<br />

states, the policy has substantial environmental and economic benefits associated<br />

with the increased recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> materials from ELVs, in addition high<br />

targets increase recycling and promote investment in eco-innovation to further<br />

increase marginal recycling rates, mainly through innovations in post-shredder<br />

technologies that mechanically sort additional materials from the automotive<br />

shredder residue (ASR).<br />

431<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


23.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

23.2.1 Europe<br />

National policies have been applied in all European countries following the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the EU ELV Directive, which came into force in 2000. 495 Member<br />

States were obliged to implement national policies by 2002. The directive was to: 496<br />

432<br />

� Ensure that all ELVs are only treated by authorised dismantlers;<br />

� Provide free take-back <strong>of</strong> all ELVs for new vehicles put on the market after<br />

2002; from 2007 provide free take-back for all vehicles including those put on<br />

market before 2002;<br />

� Restrict the use <strong>of</strong> heavy metals in vehicles from July 2003; and<br />

� Ensure that a minimum <strong>of</strong> 85% <strong>of</strong> vehicles are reused or recovered (including<br />

energy recovery) and at least 80% are reused or recycled from 2006 These<br />

rates increase to 95% and 85%, respectively, by 2015.<br />

It also requires the 'de-pollution' <strong>of</strong> vehicles before being recycled. This involves<br />

extracting petrol, diesel, brake fluid, engine oil, antifreeze, batteries, airbags, mercurybearing<br />

components and catalysts.<br />

The scope <strong>of</strong> the Directive includes cars with no more than 8 seats and goods<br />

vehicles less than 3.5t only.<br />

A small number <strong>of</strong> well administered countries with early experience <strong>of</strong> operating a<br />

highly regulated system <strong>of</strong> car disposal have been able to implement the Directive<br />

relatively smoothly. 497 The Netherlands and Sweden are good examples in this<br />

respect, with Sweden having enacted its first vehicle scrappage law in 1975 and<br />

implemented producer responsibility from 1998. Many, however, have experienced<br />

significant difficulties, delays and setbacks in implementing the Directive. Reflecting<br />

this, the Commission has taken some form <strong>of</strong> legal action against most <strong>of</strong> the EU-15<br />

Member States in relation to this Directive, in particular for late implementation. The<br />

EU-10, new Member States, have also experienced additional problems. Some<br />

examples are given in Section 23.12.<br />

23.2.2 Asia<br />

Policies have also been applied in Japan, Korea and China. However, the data and<br />

evaluation <strong>of</strong> these policies is less thorough than in the EU. These countries,<br />

especially Korea, have historically had large car manufacturing industries that have<br />

495 The End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive (2000/53/EC).<br />

496 A. Doran (2003) POLICY DISCUSSION: End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicle Directive (ELV), <strong>Policy</strong> discussion by Andy<br />

Doran from LARAC, http://www.larac.org.uk/pdf/elvbrief.pdf<br />

497 M. Fergusson and IEEP (2006) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive: An assessment <strong>of</strong> the current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> implementation by member states, Report for The European Parliament: <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Department</strong><br />

Economic and Scientific <strong>Policy</strong>.<br />

29/09/09


driven the reclamation industry to a much greater extent than other states in Asia /<br />

Indonesia.<br />

23.2.3 North America<br />

Certain Canadian provinces have regulations in place, or planned, but it is reported<br />

that there is minimal effect on waste prevention or recovery. 498 In Ontario there are<br />

municipal by-laws to govern the motor recycling industry, although, consistent<br />

monitoring <strong>of</strong> auto recycling sites (classed as ‘waste disposal sites’) is abysmal and a<br />

relevant certificate <strong>of</strong> approval has not been issued since 1979. In British Columbia<br />

there is a strong awareness <strong>of</strong> the issue and trade associations have helped devise a<br />

strategy with preventing pollution in mind. Despite these efforts, the regulations have<br />

not been enacted to date and there is no indication <strong>of</strong> when this may occur.<br />

No federal ELV polices are in place in America. Instead the largest vehicle<br />

manufacturers have formed vehicle recycling infrastructure partnerships, and actively<br />

promote the correct recovery <strong>of</strong> ELVs as part <strong>of</strong> their corporate social responsibility<br />

(CSR). In fact several <strong>of</strong> the large US companies quote the EU Directive and the ‘tough<br />

targets’ they are helping EU dismantlers to achieve. Interestingly, change in the<br />

design <strong>of</strong> vehicles to facilitate the recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> materials by American<br />

automotive manufacturers has been directly driven by their desire to sell vehicles in<br />

the EU. This is because the legislation requires any vehicle manufacturer – whether<br />

based in the EU or not – to contribute to the final cost <strong>of</strong> recovering their own models<br />

<strong>of</strong> vehicles. Thus implementation <strong>of</strong> policy in one part <strong>of</strong> the world can have<br />

significant implications for international markets around the globe.<br />

23.2.4 Country-specific Characteristics: The Netherlands<br />

There are around 8 million cars in the Netherlands, but only 0.4% <strong>of</strong> new cars sold in<br />

2005 were manufactured domestically, with the majority being imported from<br />

Germany and France. 499 Annual sales <strong>of</strong> new cars have been declining, reflecting an<br />

increase in average life. There are no significant quantities <strong>of</strong> scrapped cars imported<br />

or exported for dismantling.<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the Directive was actually inspired by the pre-existing Dutch<br />

system that was developed by the main business organisations in the car industry.<br />

The organisation ‘Auto Recycling Nederland’ (ARN) was previously established to<br />

manage the ELV treatment system. Unlike other Member States, the system operates<br />

by generating revenue from discreet fees levied on all new car registrations and used<br />

to fund the unpr<strong>of</strong>itable parts <strong>of</strong> certified car scrapping and recycling firms. The<br />

system is fully self-financing, so it could be said that the car producers and importers<br />

pay the cost <strong>of</strong> ELV management, but the cost will inevitably pass to the consumer.<br />

498 1877 End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles.com (2008) Legislation, Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://1877end<strong>of</strong>lifevehicles.com/legislation.cfm<br />

499 M. Fergusson and IEEP (2006) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive: An assessment <strong>of</strong> the current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> implementation by member states, Report for The European Parliament: <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Department</strong><br />

Economic and Scientific <strong>Policy</strong><br />

433<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


23.2.5 Country-specific Characteristics: Sweden<br />

The car industry is Sweden’s greatest exporting sector, accounting for more than 15%<br />

<strong>of</strong> total exports in 2004 (Volvo being the most common brand). 500 The total number <strong>of</strong><br />

cars has been increasing, but the proportion <strong>of</strong> cars scrapped has been declining.<br />

Sweden has a long history <strong>of</strong> legislation relating to ELVs. From the first scrappage<br />

laws in 1975 (based on a deposit refund system) to the wide-ranging ordinance on<br />

producer responsibility in 1998, both laws already covered all aspects <strong>of</strong> the EU<br />

Directive. Similarly to the Netherlands, a charge for the disposal <strong>of</strong> ELVs is levied on<br />

the sale <strong>of</strong> all new vehicles.<br />

The reporting <strong>of</strong> the targets required by the directive is controlled by the Swedish<br />

Environmental Protection Agency (SEPA). Vehicle producers must submit data which<br />

allows SEPA to assess the degree <strong>of</strong> reuse/recovery/recycling <strong>of</strong> vehicles. This is then<br />

published in annual reports on how waste subject to producer responsibility is dealt<br />

with, and includes recommendations by SEPA that address any emerging problems.<br />

In addition, the Swedish Car Recyclers Association (SBR) carries out an annual survey<br />

<strong>of</strong> its members to produce data on the number <strong>of</strong> scrapping certificates issued and<br />

quantities <strong>of</strong> waste for a number <strong>of</strong> selected materials derived from the scrap.<br />

23.2.6 Country-specific Characteristics: England<br />

The UK implemented separate parts <strong>of</strong> the ELV regulations in both 2003 and 2005.<br />

Like many other Member States, it was late doing so. 501 The implementation <strong>of</strong> take<br />

back for all cars was left until 2007 – the final date for which producers would be<br />

responsible for all vehicles placed on the market under the Directive.<br />

Under the Directive, authorised treatment facilities (ATFs) have to obtain a permit<br />

from the regulatory agencies in order to legally dispose <strong>of</strong> vehicles to a minimum<br />

technical standard. The two main service providers in the UK are Autogreen and<br />

Cartakeback. They work as industry associations to manage the network <strong>of</strong><br />

dismantlers and recyclers. The network has grown extensively, from approximately<br />

650 facilities in 2003 to 1,400 by 2006.<br />

The growth in the network has been pushed by additional regulations being<br />

implemented in the UK whereby an average 75 % <strong>of</strong> last owners should be within 10<br />

miles <strong>of</strong> the nearest ATF, and no one should be more than 30 miles (or else free take<br />

back from the home applies). 502<br />

500 M. Fergusson and IEEP (2006) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive: An assessment <strong>of</strong> the current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> implementation by member states, Report for The European Parliament: <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Department</strong><br />

Economic and Scientific <strong>Policy</strong>.<br />

501 M. Fergusson and IEEP (2006) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive: An assessment <strong>of</strong> the current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> implementation by member states, Report for The European Parliament: <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Department</strong><br />

Economic and Scientific <strong>Policy</strong>.<br />

502 In remote areas where this is not possible, one service contractor (Cartakeback) has established<br />

collection points to which vehicles can be delivered for onward transportation to an Authorised<br />

Treatment facility for de-pollution.<br />

434<br />

29/09/09


23.2.7 Country-specific Characteristics: Japan<br />

In Japan, the Ministry <strong>of</strong> <strong>International</strong> Trade and Industry passed legislation in<br />

October 1996 that adequately addressed the management and treatment <strong>of</strong> ELVs. 503<br />

It stipulated that vehicle manufacturers must decrease the amount <strong>of</strong> lead used in<br />

newly produced vehicles and also set clear targets for the recycling <strong>of</strong> ELVs. 504<br />

The Recycling Law <strong>of</strong> 2005 further substantiates the legislation to include take back<br />

responsibility for producers. It is based on a ‘shared responsibility’ principle. This is to<br />

be paid for by the implementation <strong>of</strong> a recycling fee, added on to the cost <strong>of</strong> each<br />

saleable unit. The different fees relate to the following vehicle types:<br />

435<br />

� Small and compact car;<br />

� Medium-sized car;<br />

� Tracked; and<br />

� Large bus.<br />

This fee is paid before the initial registration <strong>of</strong> the vehicle. It is collected by the Japan<br />

Automobile Recycling Promotion Centre (JARC) and is tracked through electronic<br />

manifests until the vehicle’s end <strong>of</strong> life.<br />

Reuse, recycling and recovery rates for ELVs have been set so that they mirror the<br />

European targets set out under the EU ELV Directive.<br />

If a vehicle is exported for sale or dismantling then the fee is refundable to the owner<br />

disposing <strong>of</strong> the vehicle. In the first year <strong>of</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> the policy the number <strong>of</strong><br />

ELVs decreased by a half to around 4.8 million. However, the export <strong>of</strong> used cars also<br />

increased dramatically, indicating that cars were being exported before they were<br />

classed as ELVs to take advantage <strong>of</strong> the refundable recycling fee.<br />

23.2.8 Country-specific Characteristics: South Korea<br />

There has been an obligation to take back ELVs in Korea since 1982. 505 However, in<br />

2007 the Act for Resource Recycling <strong>of</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment and<br />

Vehicles diversifies manufacturer’s responsibilities to include: 506<br />

� Restrictions on the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials;<br />

503 C. Kim (2007) A comparison <strong>of</strong> ELV system in Japan and Korea, Presentation for The Centre for<br />

Business Relationships Accountability, Sustainability and Society,<br />

http://www.brass.cf.ac.uk/uploads/elv_kim_c.pdf<br />

504 1877 End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles.com (2008) Legislation, Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://1877end<strong>of</strong>lifevehicles.com/legislation.cfm<br />

505 C. Kim (2007) A comparison <strong>of</strong> ELV system in Japan and Korea, Presentation for The Centre for<br />

Business Relationships Accountability, Sustainability and Society,<br />

http://www.brass.cf.ac.uk/uploads/elv_kim_c.pdf<br />

506 RJS Technical Consulting (2007) Act No. 6319 Resource Recycling, Accessed 20 th January 2008,<br />

http://www.rsjtechnical.com/WhatisKoreaRoHS.htm<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


436<br />

� Improvement <strong>of</strong> materials and structure in products so that they are easy to<br />

recycle;<br />

� Separate collection <strong>of</strong> waste products so that there is no cost to the person<br />

disposing <strong>of</strong> them. This includes the need for vehicle producers/importers to<br />

contract with recyclers for ELV processing;<br />

� Producers/importers <strong>of</strong> vehicles are prescribed an annual recycling target by<br />

Presidential Decree. However, since the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Act, such a<br />

Decree and hence national recycling rates have not yet been set; and<br />

� Recycling Information Network database that vehicle producers/importers can<br />

use to provide recyclers with information about material composition and<br />

recycling methods for their products, “to the extent confidential business<br />

information is not disclosed”.<br />

There is significant vehicle manufacturing in Korea, but the reprocessing industry is<br />

much larger. The number <strong>of</strong> ELVs dismantled in the country is 3 times is the number<br />

produced. Thus, nationally, the demand for ELVs exceeds the supply. This has allowed<br />

for ELVs to be sold to dismantlers on an open market and thus the obligation to take<br />

back vehicles was only required in the minority <strong>of</strong> cases.<br />

National legislation was further developed because Korea wished to develop the<br />

same high standards that are set out in the EU ELV directive. The 2007 Act provides<br />

for four different types <strong>of</strong> recyclers that process end-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicles:<br />

� Vehicle recyclers dismantle vehicles and recycle its parts to the maximum<br />

extent possible; then transfer the vehicle body and "residues" to shredders;<br />

� Vehicle shredding recyclers recover metallic materials from the residues and<br />

shred the rest <strong>of</strong> the dismantled vehicle; then transfer "shredder residues" to a<br />

residue recycler;<br />

� Vehicle shredder residue recyclers recover metallic materials from shredder<br />

residues; then recycle and/or recover energy from the residues to the<br />

maximum extent possible; and<br />

� Discarded gas recyclers who segregate and store substances that cause<br />

climate change.<br />

In several countries in the EU - notably Sweden and the Netherlands - as recycling<br />

rates increase further R&D is being undertaken into processes that recover material<br />

from the shredder residue. So it is a forward thinking part <strong>of</strong> the policy that Korea<br />

includes shredder residue recyclers in its structure.<br />

The previously poor reporting and control over standards <strong>of</strong> the recycling network in<br />

Korea has resulted in stricter mechanisms <strong>of</strong> enforcement, such as quarterly reports<br />

from the recyclers, recycling associations and vehicle producers, that are to be<br />

submitted to the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Construction and Transport. Furthermore, under the Act,<br />

any public <strong>of</strong>ficial can inspect any <strong>of</strong> the processing facilities with only 7 days prior<br />

notice to ensure that standards are being maintained.<br />

29/09/09


23.2.9 Country-specific Characteristics: China<br />

The volume <strong>of</strong> in-use vehicles in China will reach 55 million by the end <strong>of</strong> 2008 and<br />

the volume <strong>of</strong> ELVs will top 2 million this year. 507 In 2001, China passed a law<br />

regulating the disposal and recycling <strong>of</strong> ELVs, but progress has been slow, with the<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> dismantling just 10%. China has also established some ELV dismantling and<br />

disposal enterprises since 2005, but they are mostly mixed with used car sales<br />

networks, and many ELVs were resold through various channels after simple<br />

remolding.<br />

China's industry authorities have started to amend the country's rules for the recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> ELVs. The new standards regulating the disposal and recycling <strong>of</strong> ELVs are said to<br />

be in the pipeline and will published later this year. There are expected to be modeled<br />

on a market based system, as in the EU, and require similar targets. 508<br />

23.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Table 23-1 shows that the main types <strong>of</strong> organisation involved are environmental<br />

agencies, car licensing authorities and some kind <strong>of</strong> network or association <strong>of</strong><br />

recyclers.<br />

Table 23-1: Key Organisations Involved in ELV Policies<br />

437<br />

Country Country<br />

Key Key Organisations<br />

Organisations<br />

The Netherlands ‘Auto Recycling Nederland’ (ARN)<br />

Sweden<br />

England<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Swedish Environmental Protection Agency (SwEPA)<br />

Swedish Car Recyclers Association (SBR)<br />

Driver Vehicle License Authority (DVLA)<br />

AutoGreen / Cartakeback<br />

Japan Japan Automobile Recycling Promotion Centre (JARC)<br />

South Korea<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> Construction and Transport<br />

Vehicle Recycling Associations<br />

507 Gasgoo (2008) China to issue new standards <strong>of</strong> ELV recycling, Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.gasgoo.com/auto-news/6899/China-to-issue-new-standards-<strong>of</strong>-ELV-recycling-in-2008.html<br />

508 C. Kim (2007) A comparison <strong>of</strong> ELV system in Japan and Korea, Presentation for The Centre for<br />

Business Relationships Accountability, Sustainability and Society,<br />

http://www.brass.cf.ac.uk/uploads/elv_kim_c.pdf


23.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

In addition to the individual references given throughout this section, the following<br />

specific evaluation studies give useful information on the performance <strong>of</strong> ELV<br />

policies:<br />

438<br />

� Fergusson, M. and IEEP (2006) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive: An<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> the current state <strong>of</strong> implementation by member states, Report<br />

for The European Parliament: <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Department</strong> Economic and Scientific<br />

<strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

http://www.europarl.europa.eu/comparl/envi/pdf/externalexpertise/end_<strong>of</strong>_li<br />

fe_vehicles.pdf<br />

� GHK, and Bio Intelligence Service (2006) A study to examine the benefits <strong>of</strong><br />

the End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles Directive and the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> a revision <strong>of</strong><br />

the 2015 targets for recycling, re-use and recovery under the ELV Directive,<br />

Final Report to DG Environment, May 2006,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/pdf/study/final_report.pdf<br />

� Cassells, S., Holland, J. and Meister, A. (2005) End-<strong>of</strong>-life vehicle disposal:<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> proposals to resolve an environmental issue in New Zealand, Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> & Planning, Volume 7, Number 2, June 2005 , pp. 107-<br />

124(18).<br />

23.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

23.5.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

Current trends show that, both the production 509 and weight 510 <strong>of</strong> vehicles are set to<br />

increase over time. However, it is possible that people will choose smaller cars or<br />

vehicle producers, under pressure to reduce GHG emissions per mile, will reverse the<br />

trends and average vehicle weight will actually fall. Furthermore, some policies, such<br />

as in Korea, are designed to promote innovation in vehicle design so that some<br />

components are eminently more recyclable, thus preventing the final disposal <strong>of</strong> the<br />

previously unrecycled component.<br />

Alternatively, waste prevention can be achieved by reducing the hazardousness <strong>of</strong> the<br />

materials that make up the vehicle. Policies in both the EU and Asia include a phase<br />

out <strong>of</strong> heavy metals used in the manufacture <strong>of</strong> vehicles. 511<br />

509 World Watch Institute (2008) Vehicle Production Rises, But Few Cars Are “Green”, Accessed 15 th<br />

October 2008, http://www.worldwatch.org/node/5461<br />

510 GHK, and Bio Intelligence Service (2006) A study to examine the benefits <strong>of</strong> the End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

Directive and the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> a revision <strong>of</strong> the 2015 targets for recycling, re-use and recovery<br />

under the ELV Directive, Final Report to DG Environment, May 2006,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/pdf/study/final_report.pdf<br />

511 Fergusson, M. and IEEP (2006) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive: An assessment <strong>of</strong> the current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> implementation by member states, Report for The European Parliament: <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Department</strong><br />

29/09/09


In addition to the benefits associated with a reduction in heavy metals the depollution<br />

<strong>of</strong> vehicles before dismantling provides additional environmental benefits. These<br />

processes are all required by law in the countries that have implemented ELV polices<br />

and are best practice (though not necessarily widespread) in those that have not i.e.<br />

America. These processes prevent the following hazardous materials / products from<br />

causing environmental damage: 512<br />

439<br />

� Batteries;<br />

� Explosive components <strong>of</strong> airbags;<br />

� Oils, cooling liquids, anti-freeze and other liquids; and<br />

� Any parts containing mercury, cadmium etc.<br />

23.5.2 Recycling<br />

A main aim <strong>of</strong> all the ELV policies considered in this report is to increase reuse,<br />

recycling and recovery rates. This section will firstly describe the processes involved in<br />

the treatment system (including some narrative on post-shredder technologies),<br />

describe the benefits <strong>of</strong> increased recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> materials from ELVs,<br />

highlight how the targets – and the policies in general – can be measured, and finally<br />

indicate constraints to the recycling <strong>of</strong> ELVs in terms <strong>of</strong> the markets for recyclable<br />

materials.<br />

Figure 23-1 highlights the treatment processes involved in the management <strong>of</strong> ELVs.<br />

As can be seen, reuse and reprocessing from the depollution <strong>of</strong> the vehicle at an ATF<br />

is the first step involved. Further reuse <strong>of</strong> materials occurs when the vehicle is<br />

dismantled. This dismantling process has been simplified due to component coding<br />

standards and knowledge exchange promoted by the policies (See Section 23.7).<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> materials can occur from the following steps:<br />

� Initial dismantling <strong>of</strong> the vehicle;<br />

� Recovery <strong>of</strong> metals when the vehicle body is processed in an automotive<br />

shredder; and<br />

� Further separation <strong>of</strong> materials from the automotive shredder residue (ASR) -<br />

otherwise known as flock or fluff. For example, plastics separation using near<br />

infrared technology.<br />

In the EU, baseline recycling and reuse rates are around 80%, and can be obtained<br />

with little additional technology being implemented. The majority <strong>of</strong> this figure<br />

comprises <strong>of</strong> metals recycling (this level was occurring before the implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

the policy because <strong>of</strong> the high price <strong>of</strong> recycled metals) with the remainder <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Economic and Scientific <strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

http://www.europarl.europa.eu/comparl/envi/pdf/externalexpertise/end_<strong>of</strong>_life_vehicles.pdf<br />

512 US Commercial Service (2006) <strong>International</strong> Market Insight, End-<strong>of</strong>-Life-Vehicles – EU Legislation,<br />

Accessed 20 th October 2008, http://www.buyusa.gov/auto/end_<strong>of</strong>_life_vehicles_eu_design.html<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


ecycling and reuse activity being attributed to products such as tyres, glass, and a<br />

minimal quantity <strong>of</strong> plastics.<br />

Figure 23-1: Treatment Process for ELVs<br />

Source: GHK, and Bio Intelligence Service (2006) A study to examine the benefits <strong>of</strong> the End <strong>of</strong> Life<br />

Vehicles Directive and the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> a revision <strong>of</strong> the 2015 targets for recycling, re-use and<br />

recovery under the ELV Directive, Final Report to DG Environment, May 2006,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/pdf/study/final_report.pdf<br />

Countries like the Netherlands, Switzerland and Japan, are finding that the marginal<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> recycling rapidly increases above around 80% because <strong>of</strong> the labour costs<br />

involved in separating the material from the vehicle body, especially plastics, which<br />

comprise the majority <strong>of</strong> the material left after the metals, tyres and glass have been<br />

recovered post dismantling. They are increasingly using post-shredder technologies to<br />

mechanically recover additional material from the shredder residue. The norm is for<br />

this residue to be landfilled, because the cost <strong>of</strong> landfilling is currently cheaper than<br />

alternatives. Alternatively the residue can be recovered by thermal processes, but the<br />

benefits are not deemed as great as if recyclable materials can be extracted first. Two<br />

440<br />

29/09/09


key reports highlight the importance <strong>of</strong> increased innovation in this type <strong>of</strong> technology<br />

to meet the high recycling / recovery rate <strong>of</strong> 95% by 2015 (See Section 23.7). 513514<br />

The benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling, over final disposal, <strong>of</strong> the waste materials arising from ELVs<br />

can be summarised as:<br />

441<br />

� A reduction in GHG emissions associated with <strong>of</strong>fsetting virgin materials and<br />

avoided emissions from landfilling;<br />

� Reduced pollution <strong>of</strong> the natural environment from hazardous substances<br />

such as coolants and oils;<br />

� A reduction in the marginal cost <strong>of</strong> recycling as infrastructure and efficiency<br />

increases; and<br />

� Reduced levels <strong>of</strong> abandoned vehicles and associated costs to the public<br />

sector.<br />

What factors can be used to measure the achievement <strong>of</strong> recycling rates? Firstly, it is<br />

important to note that before a vehicle can be recycled it has to be legally scrapped.<br />

Illegal dumping <strong>of</strong> vehicles is being reduced, in part, as a result <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong><br />

Certificates <strong>of</strong> Destruction (CoD) that make the last registered owner <strong>of</strong> a vehicle<br />

responsible for it’s handling at the end <strong>of</strong> its life. However, the data regarding<br />

scrapping rates in Europe is sparse and <strong>of</strong> low quality, and elsewhere non-existent.<br />

The EU Directive is helping, in some respects, to provide better statistical data, but<br />

reliable time series information is not yet available. It is likely that scrappage rates<br />

are increasing, but it is not possible to directly relate this to the quantity <strong>of</strong> vehicles<br />

that are actually recycled. 515 Compounding this are other factors that affect<br />

scrappage rates such as; the average lifetime <strong>of</strong> a vehicle; vehicle sales; and the<br />

import/export <strong>of</strong> ELVs for treatment.<br />

To measure the success <strong>of</strong> the policies, one could use figures for the average<br />

recycled, recovered and reused content <strong>of</strong> a vehicle. Average recycled content rates in<br />

Japan are known to be high due to stricter targets, however, no data was found<br />

relating to the changes in actual recycling rates over time.<br />

The effect <strong>of</strong> the EU ELV Directive on recycling rates in Europe is unclear. In the most<br />

up-to-date report on the Directives’ effectiveness it is concluded that although some<br />

countries have obtained the targets early (mainly due to previous existing policies)<br />

513 M. Fergusson and IEEP (2006) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive: An assessment <strong>of</strong> the current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> implementation by member states, Report for The European Parliament: <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Department</strong><br />

Economic and Scientific <strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

http://www.europarl.europa.eu/comparl/envi/pdf/externalexpertise/end_<strong>of</strong>_life_vehicles.pdf<br />

514 GHK and Bio Intelligence Service (2006) A study to examine the benefits <strong>of</strong> the End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

Directive and the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> a revision <strong>of</strong> the 2015 targets for recycling, re-use and recovery<br />

under the ELV Directive, Final Report to DG Environment, May 2006,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/pdf/study/final_report.pdf<br />

515 Scrappage rates are the number <strong>of</strong> vehicles entering authorised treatment facilities out <strong>of</strong> the total<br />

fleet in a country, per annum.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


many are expected to fall short <strong>of</strong> the 2006 and 2015 targets. 516 A further restriction<br />

to measuring recycling rates is that many Member States have not yet implemented<br />

reliable reporting systems to allow correct measurement <strong>of</strong> how much <strong>of</strong> a vehicle is<br />

recycled or reused. Thus at the moment there are no reliable indicators to measure<br />

the performance <strong>of</strong> the ELV policies, but this will change as reporting increasing.<br />

The cost <strong>of</strong> treating ELVs is closely linked to the price <strong>of</strong> recycled metals, because a<br />

large proportion <strong>of</strong> the recycled material from ELVs will be ferrous or non-ferrous<br />

metal, both <strong>of</strong> which are relatively easy to separate for reprocessing.<br />

The recent collapse in the price <strong>of</strong> recycled metals is a situation that the ELV policies<br />

were implemented to deal with. 517 In many European countries, if the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

recovery exceed the revenue generated from the sale <strong>of</strong> recyclates the differential is<br />

funded by the vehicle producers, and in Japan, Sweden, and the Netherlands by the<br />

levy on all new vehicle registrations. Consequently, the cost to the final owner <strong>of</strong><br />

discarding the vehicle remains zero and illegal dumping is avoided. If the value <strong>of</strong><br />

recovered materials remains low, producers will need to provides additional funds to<br />

support the scheme, and this is likely to increase the cost <strong>of</strong> vehicles, at the margin.<br />

Hence, consumers will likely pay some additional amount for the increased cost <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling ELVs.<br />

GHK, and Bio Intelligence Service (2006) also concluded that the enforcement <strong>of</strong><br />

standards at ATFs increases the quality <strong>of</strong> depollution and quantity <strong>of</strong> recyclable<br />

materials recovered from the vehicle body. Consequently this is a key element to<br />

accruing the potential environmental benefits aimed for following the implementation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Directive. Therefore, some measure <strong>of</strong> poor performing states can be made in<br />

relation to how many treatment facilities are operating illegally. For example, the<br />

following list shows some indicative figures for the proportion <strong>of</strong> dismantling facilities<br />

that operate illegally in several EU Member States:<br />

442<br />

� France – 40%<br />

� Hungary – 80%<br />

� Poland – 90%<br />

23.6 Implementation Costs<br />

There will be costs involved with preliminary compliance and also with annual charges<br />

for the administration <strong>of</strong> the policy.<br />

For example, in England the preliminary compliance cost assessment estimated the<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> meeting the Directive as £360 to £520 million. This includes a cost to<br />

516 M. Fergusson and IEEP (2006) End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) Directive: An assessment <strong>of</strong> the current<br />

state <strong>of</strong> implementation by member states, Report for The European Parliament: <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>Department</strong><br />

Economic and Scientific <strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

http://www.europarl.europa.eu/comparl/envi/pdf/externalexpertise/end_<strong>of</strong>_life_vehicles.pdf<br />

517 London Metal Exchange (2009) Steel & Non-Ferrous Metals Prices, Accessed 17 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.lme.co.uk/home.asp<br />

29/09/09


Government in the form <strong>of</strong> additional running costs for the DVLA at £2 million to £7<br />

million per annum. 518 This equates at around £1 - £4 per car currently scrapped in<br />

the UK. An additional fund to cover the increase in abandoned vehicles was also<br />

provided by the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Trade and Industry to help Local Authorities with<br />

increasing clear up costs.<br />

Costs in setting up trade associations and for applying standards for ATFs and<br />

recovered materials can also imply further costs for a State implementing such<br />

policies, as can the cost <strong>of</strong> providing adequate reporting systems so that recycling<br />

targets can be measured, and developing administrative systems to manage CoD.<br />

23.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The policies should drive manufacturers to design vehicles that are easier to recycle<br />

and recovery materials from. However, GHK, and Bio Intelligence Service (2006)<br />

conclude that, notwithstanding manufacturer’s legal obligation to design vehicles in a<br />

way that they meet the recycling and recovery targets set out in the EU Directive,<br />

there is limited evidence <strong>of</strong> any significant change in vehicle design. This could be<br />

due to:<br />

443<br />

� Historic trends showing that vehicle construction materials are moving away<br />

from ferrous metals to plastics (that are harder to recycle) so industry is taking<br />

time to find novel ways to design new components with recyclability in mind; 519<br />

� The marginal costs <strong>of</strong> recycling replacement components being high, due to<br />

the labour costs involved in manual dismantling; or<br />

� A greater level <strong>of</strong> R&D into post-shredder technologies being undertaken, thus<br />

negating the need for further design improvements to the vehicles to meet<br />

higher targets. Estimates are that new processes could generate capture rates<br />

<strong>of</strong> up to 75% from the ASR. 520 This would allow for the 95% target to be met<br />

with little extra being done above the current 80% baseline. Hence if this is a<br />

more cost effective option than to redesign components to be easily recycled<br />

at the dismantlers, producers may be relying on this technology to meet the<br />

recycling and recovery targets.<br />

As highlighted in Section 23.5.2, marginal recycling and recovery rates are potentially<br />

only achievable if R&D is invested into post-shredder technologies (that can<br />

mechanically sort recyclables from the residue) in order to make further recycling<br />

cost-effective. All the main studies considered in this report indicate that the ELV<br />

518 A. Doran (2003) <strong>Policy</strong> discussion by Andy Doran from LARAC, Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.larac.org.uk/pdf/elvbrief.pdf<br />

519 <strong>Waste</strong> Online (2004) End <strong>of</strong> life vehicle and tyre recycling information sheet, Accessed 15 th October<br />

2008, http://www.wasteonline.org.uk/resources/InformationSheets/vehicle.htm<br />

520 GHK and Bio Intelligence Service (2006) A study to examine the benefits <strong>of</strong> the End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

Directive and the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> a revision <strong>of</strong> the 2015 targets for recycling, re-use and recovery<br />

under the ELV Directive, Final Report to DG Environment, May 2006,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/pdf/study/final_report.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


policies are directly driving this R&D. GHK, and Bio Intelligence Service proposes that<br />

Member States might consider banning ASR from landfill in order to further send a<br />

signal to the industry and speed up R&D. 521<br />

In the EU the ELV Directive includes a coding standards obligation whereby the<br />

producers must, in concert with material and equipment manufacturers, use the<br />

nomenclature <strong>of</strong> ISO component and material coding standards for the labeling and<br />

identification <strong>of</strong> components and materials <strong>of</strong> vehicles, and in Korea, for example, a<br />

Recycling Information Network has been set up to make it easier for dismantlers to<br />

identify the parts <strong>of</strong> the vehicle that can be either reused or recycled.<br />

This is most relevant to plastics that are difficult to separate due to the wide variety <strong>of</strong><br />

polymer types. Kvist also indicates that to achieve the high recycling rates designs<br />

should be modified to include materials codings to ease identification <strong>of</strong> parts<br />

(especially plastics) and to avoid risk substances. 522<br />

GHK, and Bio Intelligence Service points out that there is a strong dialogue between<br />

producers, dismantlers and automotive shedding facilities in relation to what<br />

components or materials are causing issues in the recovery and shredding processes.<br />

For example, some adhesives that affix textiles and plastic components to the vehicle<br />

body cause problems when it comes to separating materials from the ASR. Therefore<br />

tests are being performed as to what adhesive will meet the standards <strong>of</strong> the<br />

producers, but also enable the highest capture rates <strong>of</strong> materials from the ASR.<br />

Finally, in Sweden, where the population density is low, there were some problems<br />

with illegal dumping because people were unwilling to transport their vehicles to an<br />

ATF. So to continue to increase their recycling and recovery rates, mobile depollution<br />

and dismantling units have been developed to travel around the country to capture<br />

vehicles that may otherwise have been dumped.<br />

23.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

There are not thought to be any distributional consequences as the Directive applies<br />

to a wide range <strong>of</strong> vehicles. The policy may in fact help to alleviate distributional<br />

issues where, without producer responsibility, the cost <strong>of</strong> disposal previously fell to<br />

the final owner <strong>of</strong> vehicles – individuals who (by nature <strong>of</strong> owning lower priced cars)<br />

might be expected to be less able to afford disposal fees, and hence were more likely<br />

to abandon them illegally.<br />

In addition, in many countries (including the UK) the incidence <strong>of</strong> car ownership is low<br />

in the poorest sections <strong>of</strong> society. Hence, even if it was the case that some costs had<br />

to be born by the final owners, the very poorest sectors <strong>of</strong> society might not be heavily<br />

521 GHK and Bio Intelligence Service (2006) A study to examine the benefits <strong>of</strong> the End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles<br />

Directive and the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> a revision <strong>of</strong> the 2015 targets for recycling, re-use and recovery<br />

under the ELV Directive, Final Report to DG Environment, May 2006,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/pdf/study/final_report.pdf<br />

522 K. Kvist (2006) Car Recycling and Producer Responsibility – Sweden, Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://www3.gov.ab.ca/env/waste/eprw/pubs/Karin_Kvist.pdf<br />

444<br />

29/09/09


affected. In any event, the effect on new car prices is likely to be very limited in most<br />

cases when considered as a proportion <strong>of</strong> total costs.<br />

23.9 Complementary Policies<br />

The following policies may all be considered to help deliver (or potentially deliver) the<br />

objectives <strong>of</strong> ELV producer responsibility:<br />

445<br />

� Producer responsibility policies – ELV policies tend to be a subset <strong>of</strong> more<br />

general producer responsibility policy;<br />

� Landfill Directive – For tyres;<br />

� Landfill bans i.e. on ELVs or ASR;<br />

� The <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration Directive – for setting limit values and other conditions<br />

on co-incineration <strong>of</strong> waste tyres / ASR;<br />

� EU Batteries Directive – batteries fall under the directive when they are<br />

removed from the vehicles for reuse / reprocessing;<br />

� Controlled <strong>Waste</strong> Act 1990 (tyres) – the recycling network for cars made the<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> tyres more cost effective;<br />

� Vehicle Licensing – as stricter licensing will discourage people from<br />

abandoning cars in the first place; and<br />

� Vehicle Laws – in Asian countries these are in place to limit vehicle<br />

abandonment etc.<br />

23.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

As discussed in Section 23.5.2, the price <strong>of</strong> new vehicles will go up in the long term<br />

as producers pass the cost <strong>of</strong> managing ELVs through to the consumer.<br />

At the margin, plastics are the next material to be focused on as current recycling<br />

rates are low compared with those for metals. Therefore, the boost in investment for<br />

automotive shredder and plastics recycling processes (see Section 23.7) could see a<br />

fall in the marginal cost <strong>of</strong> treatment at these types <strong>of</strong> facilities, and also a reduction<br />

in the price for recycled plastics as more material is available in the market.<br />

23.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

It is an <strong>of</strong>fence to fail to comply with the law on the disposal <strong>of</strong> ELVs. Failure to comply<br />

can results in fines or convictions resulting in custodial sentences.<br />

There is no information regarding evasion and enforcement from the Asian countries.<br />

The following points indicate some European examples:<br />

� CoD were not needed in England if a tick box on the vehicle registration<br />

document was marked indicating that the owner had scrapped the vehicle<br />

themselves. This may have led to increased illegal activity so the DVLA is<br />

considering whether this alternative means <strong>of</strong> notification should be<br />

withdrawn;<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


446<br />

� Action has been taken against The Netherlands because <strong>of</strong> issues concerning<br />

the definition <strong>of</strong> ‘treatment’ and the promotion <strong>of</strong> certified environmental<br />

management systems in treatment plants; and<br />

� In 2003, the European Court <strong>of</strong> Justice condemned the UK for non<br />

transposition <strong>of</strong> the Directive by the time required (21 April 2002) and<br />

condemned the UK government to pay the costs <strong>of</strong> judgment.<br />

GHK, and Bio Intelligence Service (2006) concluded that neither the environmental or<br />

economic benefits are fully realised because <strong>of</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong> full implementation and<br />

enforcement <strong>of</strong> the Directive.<br />

Some mitigation <strong>of</strong> illegal activities could be provided if the country implements an<br />

‘own marque’ scheme. 523 It is believed that this responsibility will mean that vehicle<br />

manufacturers will have more <strong>of</strong> a direct interest in their own vehicles, from, as it<br />

were, ‘cradle to grave’, and thus will have an incentive to minimise the likelihood <strong>of</strong><br />

their vehicles ending up being used illegally, where they can exercise some control<br />

over this. However, in the UK, for example, producers may discharge their obligations<br />

by contracting with authorised treatment facilities (ATFs) or by entering into<br />

arrangements with the motor insurance industry and/or vehicle salvage operators<br />

directly. Hence, no strong evidence exists to support the argument either way.<br />

Additionally, the European Union Network for the Implementation and Enforcement <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental Law (IMPEL) is concerned about the level <strong>of</strong> illegal shipments <strong>of</strong> ELVs.<br />

Czararnomski et al note that some enforcement issues have arisen because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

disparity in definitions between ‘waste’ and ‘second hand goods’. 524 Furthermore, a<br />

final conclusion is that the ELV directive has had the likely effect <strong>of</strong> increasing illegal<br />

exports, particularly to Africa and Eastern Europe. To further clarify these issues a<br />

paper is being prepared by Ireland with the aim to carry out a threat assessment on<br />

the Transfrontier Shipment <strong>of</strong> waste (TFS) from the European Union. This study was<br />

still included on IMPEL’s 2008 work programme, so it is not thought that it has been<br />

published to date.<br />

23.12 Lessons Learned<br />

As an EU Member State Ireland is obligated to meet the requirements and targets set<br />

out in the ELV Directive. The following points highlight the main issues that could be<br />

useful to a country aiming to both meet these targets on time, and improve<br />

environmental performance from the treatment <strong>of</strong> their ELVs:<br />

� Effective Effective phase phase out out <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> heavy heavy metals: metals: The phase out <strong>of</strong> heavy metals has been<br />

effective due to the clear signal given to the industry that this was going to<br />

523 DTI (2005) Full Regulatory Impact Assessment (RIA) for the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Trade and Industry’s<br />

Statutory Instrument, The End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (Producer responsibility) Regulations 2005, Transposing<br />

Articles 5 and 7 <strong>of</strong> Directive 2000/53/EC1 <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council on End <strong>of</strong><br />

Life Vehicles in the UK, Report for DTI.<br />

524 S. Czararnomski, A. Holmes and B. Webb (2006) IMPEL_TFS THREAT ASSESSMENT PROJECT: The<br />

Illegal Shipment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Among IMPEL Member States, Project Report for IMPEL.<br />

29/09/09


447<br />

happen and because a reasonable amount <strong>of</strong> time was provided to allow<br />

vehicle producers to comply;<br />

� Potential Potential for for phase phase out out <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> other other materials: materials: materials: Further phase out <strong>of</strong> additional<br />

materials (such as certain plastics that are difficult to recycle) could therefore<br />

be effective based on this evidence if a clear signal and adequate time was<br />

given for producers to comply;<br />

� Regulation Regulation Regulation <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> all all all dismantling dismantling dismantling operations operations operations is is is crucial: crucial: crucial: The prevention <strong>of</strong><br />

hazardous wastes, such as coolants and oils, from entering the environment is<br />

also a key result <strong>of</strong> the policy, and is maintained by the strict depollution<br />

regulations. However, these regulations are only enforced at authorised<br />

treatment facilities (ATFs). Hence the regulation and control <strong>of</strong> any dismantling<br />

operation is a key element to maintaining environmental performance;<br />

� Control Control <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> ATFs ATFs increases increases efficiency: efficiency: efficiency: The control over ATFs has been shown to<br />

promote efficiency and therefore increase the average recycled content <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ELVs being processed. Therefore, this is also a key element to obtaining high<br />

recycling and recovery rates;<br />

� Presence Presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> industry industry associations associations supports supports the the ELV ELV treatment treatment system: system:<br />

In all<br />

the countries where the policies have had the most success, such as Japan,<br />

Sweden and the Netherlands, there are industry associations governing the<br />

operation <strong>of</strong> the ATFs, managing free take back <strong>of</strong> ELVs and liaising with<br />

vehicle producers. The emergence <strong>of</strong> associations can be related to the size <strong>of</strong><br />

the vehicle producing industry in that country. Conversely, in countries such as<br />

Hungary and Poland, where there are still many illegally operating facilities and<br />

the overall recycling rates are low, there are no significant industry<br />

associations. Thus an important aspect <strong>of</strong> any successful ELV reprocessing<br />

system is a well engaged industry association willing to take on some<br />

responsibility and promote best practice; and<br />

� Use Use <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> mechanical mechanical separation separation separation technologies technologies to to recover recover material material from from ASR ASR is<br />

is<br />

considered considered the the most most cost cost effective effective way way to to meet meet future future recycling recycling and and recov recovery recov recovery<br />

ery<br />

targets: targets: Countries such as Japan, Korea, Sweden, Switzerland and the<br />

Netherlands are all finding that the marginal cost <strong>of</strong> recovery from manual<br />

dismantling increases sharply after a baseline <strong>of</strong> 80% to 85% is achieved.<br />

Little headway has been made by manufacturers in designing components to<br />

be easily dismantled and recycled. Thus investment is being made in postshredder<br />

technologies whereby additional mechanical sorting <strong>of</strong> the<br />

automotive shredder residue (ASR) is made to recover a greater range <strong>of</strong><br />

materials (general consensus is that mechanical sorting <strong>of</strong> the ASR is more<br />

beneficial than energy recovery in terms <strong>of</strong> environmental performance and<br />

the attainment <strong>of</strong> recycling and recovery rates). Investment in this type <strong>of</strong><br />

technology should therefore be promoted, whether it is through direct grants<br />

from government or the EC, or by implementing regulatory drivers such as a<br />

ban on landfilling <strong>of</strong> ASR. Furthermore, a strong link between the technology<br />

providers / operators and vehicle manufactures is recommended to optimise<br />

the whole system.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


24.0 Producer Responsibility, Batteries - Ireland<br />

24.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Ireland’s <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Batteries and Accumulators) Regulations (S.I No. 268<br />

<strong>of</strong> 2008) transposes the EU Directive 2006/66/EU on waste batteries into national<br />

legislation. The EU Directive aims to minimise the negative impact <strong>of</strong> waste batteries<br />

and accumulators on the environment, and to harmonise the heavy metal content<br />

and labelling <strong>of</strong> batteries and accumulators across the European market.<br />

The EU Directive aims to recycle 25% <strong>of</strong> portable batteries by 2012 with a target <strong>of</strong><br />

45% <strong>of</strong> all waste batteries to be recycled by 2016. WEEE (<strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and<br />

Electronic Equipment) Ireland, the authorised compliance scheme for electronic and<br />

battery recycling in Ireland, is currently rolling out its battery recycling programme<br />

which will see 50,000 waste battery drop-<strong>of</strong>f boxes being delivered to 10,000 retail<br />

outlets throughout the country.<br />

According to the Batteries Directive there are three distinct battery classifications –<br />

industrial, automotive and portable (usually defined as sealed and hand carried).<br />

Whilst it is clear to which sector <strong>of</strong> the economy industrial batteries belong, portable<br />

batteries are used across consumer, commercial and industrial sectors (though the<br />

vast majority are used in consumer applications). Automotive batteries also straddle<br />

all three sectors.<br />

As noted in the Directive, “batteries” is used to mean single-life batteries (sometimes<br />

also referred to as ‘primary’ batteries), and “accumulators” to mean rechargeable<br />

batteries (sometimes also referred to as ‘secondary’ batteries). In this report<br />

“batteries” is taken to mean both batteries and accumulators, unless otherwise<br />

specified.<br />

It is estimated that in addition to automotive batteries, which are mostly recycled,<br />

around 2,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> portable batteries are sold in Ireland each year with the vast<br />

majority being discarded as residual waste instead <strong>of</strong> being recycled due their small<br />

size. 525 The regulations provide for the free take-back <strong>of</strong> all waste batteries and<br />

accumulators, otherwise known as rechargeable batteries, in-store and at designated<br />

locations.<br />

Taken with the continued implementation <strong>of</strong> the WEEE and RoHS Directives,<br />

transposition <strong>of</strong> the new Batteries Directive will complete a comprehensive corpus <strong>of</strong><br />

EU and national legislation for the EEE (Electrical and Electronic Equipment) sector.<br />

The Directive will facilitate the effective environmental management <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

batteries.<br />

525 WEEE Ireland, News Release, 13 th August 2008, “Countdown Underway to New Battery Recycling<br />

Scheme”.<br />

448<br />

29/09/09


24.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The Batteries Directive is a Producer Responsibility Initiative (similar to WEEE, RoHS,<br />

packaging, end <strong>of</strong> life vehicles and tyres) whereby the person who places the product<br />

on the market has responsibility for financing the collection, storage, recycling and<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> the product when it becomes waste.<br />

Any person who supplies batteries to the Irish market, whether as retailers, importers<br />

or manufacturers has obligations.<br />

For example:<br />

449<br />

� Retailers must now take back waste batteries free <strong>of</strong> charge <strong>of</strong> the type that<br />

they sell – for instance, if one sells portable batteries such as types AAA, AA,<br />

Cell C, Cell D, or PP3. Retailers who only see portable batteries one will not be<br />

obliged to take back automotive, industrial or small sealed lead acid batteries<br />

for alarms;<br />

� Retailers <strong>of</strong> automotive and industrial batteries must register with their local<br />

authority; and<br />

� Retailers may deposit waste portable batteries free <strong>of</strong> charge at local authority<br />

civic amenity facilities. 526<br />

Consumers should not throw waste batteries into the household waste or recycling<br />

bin, but avail <strong>of</strong> the free recycling that will be available at all retail outlets that supply<br />

batteries, and at civic amenity sites. 527<br />

Automotive and industrial batteries are much more homogenous in composition than<br />

portable batteries, nearly all consisting <strong>of</strong> lead acid batteries. Due to the high<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> lead in these batteries and the inherent value <strong>of</strong> this material recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> these battery categories is common practice and as such collection rates are<br />

already very high (in excess <strong>of</strong> 90%).<br />

While lead prices are subject to fluctuations, the collection infrastructure for these<br />

batteries is well established and as such the main emphasis <strong>of</strong> the Directive is to<br />

increase the number <strong>of</strong> portable batteries collected for recycling.<br />

24.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The Directive was implemented in full in Ireland on the 26 th September 2008 – the<br />

deadline required to transpose the Directive into national law.<br />

526 DoEHLG (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> Batteries and the Retailer,<br />

www.environ.ie/en/Environment/<strong>Waste</strong>/ProducerResponsibilityObiligation/Batteries<br />

527 EPA (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> Batteries and Accumulators, www.epa.ie/whatwedo/resource/battery/<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


24.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The WEEE Register Society Ltd was set up as a national producer registration body to<br />

assist producers in meeting their obligations for the responsible management <strong>of</strong><br />

WEEE. It will also handle this function in relation to the Batteries Directive. The<br />

registration system operated by WEEE Register is self-financing with the necessary<br />

funding coming from the obligated producers. 528 The WEEE Register has a duty to<br />

notify the EPA <strong>of</strong> any non-compliance.<br />

WEEE Ireland and ERP Ireland are the two approved national compliance schemes<br />

which collect waste batteries for recycling on behalf <strong>of</strong> their members and reports on<br />

this process to the regulatory bodies. The two companies operate in distinct<br />

geographical areas as follows:<br />

450<br />

� ERP Ireland, collect in the functional areas <strong>of</strong> Limerick City Council and Cavan,<br />

Clare, Fingal, Kerry, Limerick, Meath and Monaghan County Councils; and<br />

� WEEE Ireland, collect in the functional areas <strong>of</strong> all the remaining local<br />

authorities.<br />

The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) and local authorities have enforcement<br />

roles under the legislation. In general terms, the EPA is responsible for enforcing<br />

producer obligations and local authorities for distributor obligations. The EPA will be<br />

empowered to order the withdrawal and recall <strong>of</strong> non-compliant batteries from the<br />

market and seek an injunction against a person failing to comply with a direction to<br />

withdraw or recall non-compliant batteries, in lieu <strong>of</strong> instigating summary<br />

proceedings. An appeals mechanism will, however, be available to effected<br />

producers.<br />

24.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

No evaluation <strong>of</strong> policy has been carried out since the recent introduction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Batteries Directive in Ireland. The WEEE Register oversees the ‘WEEE Blackbox’ – an<br />

information gathering service whose role includes:<br />

• Receipt and processing <strong>of</strong> data on market share from registered producers<br />

(per weight, chemistry, category and subcategory);<br />

• Determination <strong>of</strong> market share based on battery type and producer; and<br />

• Providing management reports for WEEE Register.<br />

Information is submitted to the ‘WEEE Blackbox’ on a monthly basis and began in<br />

February 2009. The purpose <strong>of</strong> the data input is to determine the financial liability by<br />

market share <strong>of</strong> individual producers. No information has been made public at the<br />

528 <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Batteries and Accumulators) Regulations 2008 (S.I. No. 268 <strong>of</strong> 2008)<br />

29/09/09


time <strong>of</strong> writing, though it is understood that an annual review/report <strong>of</strong> the scheme<br />

will be publicly available.<br />

24.6 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

No evaluation <strong>of</strong> policy in Ireland has been carried out since the introduction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Batteries Directive on the 26 th September 2008. 529 Previous studies were carried out<br />

in order to calculate waste arisings – all battery producers, through their<br />

representative associations, were requested to provide data on the quantities <strong>of</strong><br />

batteries placed on the market in Ireland. The quantities reported as being placed on<br />

the market are shown in Table 24-1.<br />

Table 24-1: Quantities <strong>of</strong> Batteries Placed on the Market<br />

Type Type<br />

Weight Weight (Tonnes)<br />

(Tonnes)<br />

Portable Batteries and Button Cells excluding NiCd 685<br />

Portable NiCd Batteries 4<br />

Lead Acid Automotive and Industrial 8,410<br />

Total Total<br />

9,099<br />

9,099<br />

Source: DoEHLG, RIA Report, 2008<br />

Based on this limited information provided by producers, and the achievement <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Directive collection rate targets (including incremental progress leading up to and<br />

following the achievement <strong>of</strong> those estimated targets) quantities <strong>of</strong> portable batteries<br />

diverted from final disposal would need to be as shown in Table 24-2.<br />

Note that some producers failed to submit information citing reasons <strong>of</strong> commercial<br />

confidentiality. Therefore quantities, particularly <strong>of</strong> portable batteries, placed on the<br />

market are believed to be understated.<br />

The UK’s <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Food, and Rural Affairs (DEFRA) commissioned<br />

a report in 2008 into life-cycle assessment for separately collecting and recycling<br />

portable batteries in the UK according to the requirements <strong>of</strong> the new Batteries<br />

Directive. In this study it is estimated that 24,850 tonnes <strong>of</strong> portable batteries were<br />

placed on the UK market in 2003. The population in the UK in 2003 was 59.55<br />

million. 530 In Ireland the population in 2003 was 3.98 million. Due to similarities in<br />

the Irish and UK markets extrapolation is a reasonable method <strong>of</strong> calculating the<br />

quantities <strong>of</strong> batteries placed on the market. Such an extrapolation would suggest<br />

1,660 tonnes <strong>of</strong> portable batteries were placed on the Irish market in 2003.<br />

529 A telephone conversation with a member <strong>of</strong> ERP, indicated that monitoring <strong>of</strong> recycling targets for<br />

batteries will commence in February 2009. Report will be updated as soon as information is made<br />

available.<br />

530 DoEHLG (2008) “<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Batteries & Accumulators) Regulations 2008 (S.I No.268 <strong>of</strong><br />

2008), Screening Regulatory Impact Analysis”.<br />

451<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Producers <strong>of</strong> portable batteries are required to achieve collection rates <strong>of</strong> 25% (415<br />

tonnes) by 26 September 2012 and 45% (747 tonnes) by 26 September 2016.<br />

Table 24-2: Quantities <strong>of</strong> Portable Batteries Requiring Diversion from Final Disposal<br />

According to Producers<br />

452<br />

29/09/09<br />

Date Date<br />

Collection Collection Rate<br />

Rate<br />

Tonnes Tonnes Diverted Diverted from from from Final<br />

Disposal<br />

Disposal<br />

2009 10% 69<br />

2010 15% 103<br />

2011 20% 138<br />

2012 25% 172<br />

2013 30% 207<br />

2014 35% 241<br />

2015 40% 275<br />

2016 45% 310<br />

2017 50% 344<br />

2018 55% 379<br />

Source: DoEHLG, RIA Report, 2008<br />

This estimate extrapolated from the 2008 DEFRA report would suggest that contrary<br />

to the figures quoted in Table 24-2, the quantities <strong>of</strong> portable batteries requiring<br />

diversion from final disposal could in fact be as high as the figures shown in Table<br />

24-3. Unfortunately no reliable baseline information exists for the portable battery<br />

collection rate prior to the introduction <strong>of</strong> the Directive, but given the limited collection<br />

infrastructure at that time this is believed to be less than 1%.<br />

Table 24-3: Quantities <strong>of</strong> Portable Batteries Requiring Diversion from Final Disposal<br />

According to Extrapolation from UK Arisings Figures<br />

Date Date<br />

Collection Collection Rate<br />

Rate<br />

Tonnes Tonnes Diverted Diverted from from from Final<br />

Disposal<br />

Disposal<br />

2009 10% 166<br />

2010 15% 249<br />

2011 20% 332<br />

2012 25% 415<br />

2013 30% 498<br />

2014 35% 581<br />

2015 40% 664<br />

2016 45% 747<br />

2017 50% 830<br />

2018 55% 913<br />

Source: DoEHLG, RIA Report, 2008


24.7 Environmental Benefits<br />

The Batteries Directive aims to minimise the negative impact <strong>of</strong> waste batteries and<br />

accumulators on the environment, and to harmonise the heavy metal content and<br />

labelling <strong>of</strong> batteries and accumulators across the European market.<br />

Most batteries contain heavy metals (mercury, cadmium, lead), which are the main<br />

cause for environmental concern. If waste batteries are not disposed <strong>of</strong> correctly,<br />

heavy metals may leak when the battery corrodes, and so contribute to soil and water<br />

pollution and endanger wildlife. The main environmental objective is to create a<br />

closed-loop system for all batteries to avoid their incineration or disposal in a landfill<br />

(Section 25.5 explores in more detail the environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> the Directive).<br />

24.8 Implementation Costs<br />

Producers will be required to finance any net costs arising from the collection,<br />

storage, treatment and recovery and/or disposal <strong>of</strong> waste batteries including those<br />

incorporated into EEE and/or battery packs, any public information campaign on the<br />

collection, storage, treatment and recovery and/or disposal <strong>of</strong> portable batteries.<br />

Each producer shall be required to collect, as a minimum, no later than 26<br />

September 2012, 25%, and 26 September 2016, 45% <strong>of</strong> the quantity by type <strong>of</strong><br />

portable battery he or she places on the market. 531<br />

Reliable data is not available to accurately estimate the full cost implications <strong>of</strong> the<br />

new scheme in Ireland. Based on the limited information provided by producers<br />

regarding quantities placed on the market it is estimated that at the very least annual<br />

producer costs for the environmentally sound management <strong>of</strong> waste portable<br />

batteries would be the lower range shown in Table 24-4.<br />

Based on the extrapolated data from the DEFRA report referenced in section 24.6<br />

and information provided by local authorities concerning costs incurred in having<br />

waste batteries deposited at civic amenity sites collected, an upper range (and<br />

perhaps more realistic) is also shown in Table 24-4. It should be noted that the cost<br />

per tonne for both these scenarios is estimated at €1,710.<br />

Local authorities have indicated that the costs associated with managing waste<br />

batteries deposited at civic amenity sites are minimal. It is also believed that any<br />

additional costs related to enforcing the Regulations would be small given the<br />

synergies with the existing WEEE requirements. The wide variation in the estimated<br />

costs reflects the paucity <strong>of</strong> reliable information on which to base an accurate<br />

estimation.<br />

531 <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Batteries and Accumulators) Regulations 2008 (S.I. No. 268 <strong>of</strong> 2008)<br />

453<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 24-4 Estimated Producer Costs for <strong>Waste</strong> Battery Disposal<br />

454<br />

12 12 Months Months End End 25<br />

25<br />

September<br />

September<br />

29/09/09<br />

Collection Collection Collection Rate Rate<br />

Annual Annual Cost<br />

Cost<br />

2009 10% € 117,765 – 283,913<br />

2010 15% € 176,648 – 425,870<br />

2011 20% € 235,531 – 567,826<br />

2012 25% € 294,413 – 709,783<br />

2013 30% € 353,296 – 851,739<br />

2014 35% € 412,178 – 993,696<br />

2015 40% € 471,061 – 1,135,653<br />

2016 45% € 529,944 – 1,277,609<br />

2017 50% € 588,826 – 1,419,566<br />

2018 55% € 647,709 – 1,561,522<br />

Source: DoEHLG, RIA Report, 2008<br />

24.9 Response from Public and Industry<br />

In order to minimise the impact implementation <strong>of</strong> the Directive will have on<br />

businesses, the Regulations specifically provide for:<br />

� An exemption for retailers from having to have a valid waste collection permit<br />

and valid waste permit;<br />

� Permitting EEE and battery retailers to use composite point <strong>of</strong> sale / display<br />

signage;<br />

� Producers having the option to establish and maintain their own registration<br />

system; and<br />

� The removal <strong>of</strong> the burden for individual compliance by permitting producers<br />

to participate in collective compliance schemes.<br />

It is too early to gauge the strength <strong>of</strong> response from the public and no data is<br />

available as at the time <strong>of</strong> writing to evaluate performance. It is clear that such an<br />

evaluation will be made more difficult by the lack <strong>of</strong> quality data regarding the<br />

baseline tonnages <strong>of</strong> batteries in the market.<br />

24.10 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Any innovation on the battery industry, whether linked to evolving battery chemistry<br />

composition or sorting/reprocessing improvements will not be isolated to any<br />

Member State. These technology changes are happening in a global context and are<br />

discussed in Section 25.8.


24.11 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The right to free take-back <strong>of</strong> waste batteries will apply equally to people living in<br />

urban and rural communities. When fully operational, the waste battery recovery<br />

scheme will provide a network <strong>of</strong> authorised collection facilities spread throughout<br />

the country, thereby providing local access to waste battery take back arrangements.<br />

Members <strong>of</strong> the public may continue to avail <strong>of</strong> the free take-back service provided at<br />

Civic Amenity sites. Schools and workplaces may also continue to provide free<br />

convenient collection points for students/employees, but the premises must be<br />

designated by their Local Authority in order to continue providing the collection point.<br />

The changes required as a result the Directive are likely to lead to employment<br />

opportunities <strong>of</strong> a broad range (from manual to highly skilled) in Ireland. The possible<br />

impacts at the EU level are discussed in Section 25.9.<br />

24.12 Complementary Policies<br />

These are principally other EU Directives and are discussed in section 25.10.<br />

24.13 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

Due to the only recent transposition <strong>of</strong> the Directive, it is as yet unknown if an<br />

increase in battery prices will follow as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the additional financial<br />

commitments on producers.<br />

24.14 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The EPA and local authorities have enforcement roles under the Batteries Directive.<br />

In general terms, the EPA is responsible for enforcing producer obligations and local<br />

authorities for distributor obligations. As with other directives <strong>of</strong> this kind the<br />

enforcement agencies tend to take a ‘light-touch’ approach (i.e. raising awareness<br />

rather than using the full-force <strong>of</strong> the law) during an initial period as those affected by<br />

the regulations become familiar. This position then tends to gradually tighten as<br />

genuine evasion becomes apparent.<br />

24.15 Lessons Learned<br />

Ireland has opted to follow the lead <strong>of</strong> other Member States who have been able to<br />

deliver high collection rates via a network <strong>of</strong> collection points (see section 25.6). The<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> collection points in Ireland is one per every 400 inhabitants, which is<br />

equal to that in top performing countries such as Belgium and Germany indicating a<br />

high level <strong>of</strong> scheme convenience for the public. 532<br />

Whilst level <strong>of</strong> service is undoubtedly a key factor in the success <strong>of</strong> any collection<br />

scheme it is critical the public at large is aware <strong>of</strong> such services and how to use them.<br />

Given the extremely low starting level <strong>of</strong> portable battery collection rates in Ireland it<br />

532 Based on 10,000 retailer take-back serving a population <strong>of</strong> 4 million inhabitants.<br />

455<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


is only to be expected that significant resources will need to be put into an extensive<br />

education and communications campaign that is capable <strong>of</strong> fundamentally changing<br />

attitudes and behaviour, and that achieving such change may take considerable time.<br />

Evidence is not yet available to indicate whether Ireland is on course to meet its<br />

collection obligations under the Directive. If Ireland’s collection rates remain low in a<br />

scenario <strong>of</strong> high publicity, it may have to reconsider the ‘one-size-fits-all’ approach <strong>of</strong><br />

retailer take-back and consider other collection methods (possibly in specific<br />

geographical areas such as rural communities). These alternatives are discussed in<br />

Section 25.6.<br />

456<br />

29/09/09


25.0 Producer Responsibility, Batteries -<br />

<strong>International</strong><br />

25.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The foremost piece <strong>of</strong> international producer responsibility legislation affecting the<br />

waste prevention <strong>of</strong> batteries is the EU Batteries and Accumulators and <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Batteries and Accumulators Directive (2006/66/EC) (hereafter “the Batteries<br />

Directive”). Batteries, along with three other waste streams subject to EC producer<br />

responsibility directives (Packaging, WEEE and ELV), were identified in the EU’s Fifth<br />

Environment Action Programme as a “priority waste stream” due to increasing<br />

concern <strong>of</strong> the adverse impact <strong>of</strong> battery waste on the environment. Sustainability is<br />

therefore at the heart <strong>of</strong> such policies.<br />

Whilst this Directive incorporates elements that could be considered as separate<br />

policies (i.e. outright ban on sending certain types <strong>of</strong> batteries to landfill or<br />

incineration), the Batteries Directive is principally concerned with producer<br />

responsibility. It should, however, be noted that there are other countries with<br />

producer responsibility policies for batteries, notably Canada, USA, Brazil, Japan and<br />

South Korea and many others are also in the process <strong>of</strong> considering such legislation.<br />

25.1.1 EU <strong>Policy</strong><br />

According to the Batteries Directive there are three distinct battery classifications –<br />

industrial, automotive and portable (usually defined as sealed and hand carried).<br />

Whilst it is clear to which sector <strong>of</strong> the economy industrial batteries belong, portable<br />

batteries are used across consumer, commercial and industrial sectors (though the<br />

vast majority are used in consumer applications). Automotive batteries also straddle<br />

all three sectors.<br />

As noted in the Directive, “batteries” is used to mean single-life batteries (sometimes<br />

also referred to as ‘primary’ batteries), and “accumulators” to mean rechargeable<br />

batteries (sometimes also referred to as ‘secondary’ batteries). In this report<br />

“batteries” is taken to mean both batteries and accumulators, unless otherwise<br />

specified.<br />

The intended impact <strong>of</strong> the Batteries Directive is to improve the environmental<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> batteries and <strong>of</strong> the activities <strong>of</strong> all economic operators involved in<br />

the life cycle <strong>of</strong> batteries.<br />

Key provisions <strong>of</strong> the Directive are:<br />

457<br />

� Restrictions on the use <strong>of</strong> mercury (0.0005%) and cadmium (0.002%) in all<br />

batteries by weight (with the exception <strong>of</strong> button cells at 2%);<br />

� Labelling requirements for new batteries to aid consumer choice and recycling;<br />

� A 25% collection rate for waste portable batteries to be met by September<br />

2012, rising to 45% by September 2016;<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


458<br />

� A prohibition on the disposal by landfill or incineration <strong>of</strong> waste industrial and<br />

automotive batteries – in effect setting a 100% collection and recycling target;<br />

� The introduction <strong>of</strong> “producer responsibility” obligations;<br />

� The setting <strong>of</strong> recycling efficiencies to ensure that a high proportion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

weight <strong>of</strong> waste batteries is recycled (65% <strong>of</strong> lead acid batteries, 75% <strong>of</strong><br />

nickel-cadmium batteries and 50% <strong>of</strong> other waste batteries); and<br />

� The setting <strong>of</strong> waste battery treatment standards.<br />

Member State implementation <strong>of</strong> the Directive reflects these objectives. The<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the Batteries Directive is broadly similar across Member States,<br />

with mercury and cadmium limits being universal, alongside producer responsibility<br />

policies to cover the costs <strong>of</strong> campaigns to inform the public, and to implement, the<br />

new arrangements. Producer responsibility requires (article 8 <strong>of</strong> the Batteries<br />

Directive):<br />

29/09/09<br />

“distributors to take back waste portable batteries or accumulators at no<br />

charge when supplying portable batteries or accumulators, unless an<br />

assessment shows that alternative existing schemes are at least as effective<br />

in attaining the environmental aims <strong>of</strong> this Directive. Member States shall<br />

make public such assessments”.<br />

It should be emphasised that the Battery Directive leaves considerable freedom to<br />

the Member States and their national legislation with respect to the organisation <strong>of</strong><br />

collection systems. It only specifies that batteries can be collected (1) individually (2)<br />

by way <strong>of</strong> national battery collection schemes or (3) together with the WEEE collection<br />

schemes. A similar freedom applies to the actual physical infrastructure that is used.<br />

For instance, in Belgium, schools are used as collection points, while in some other<br />

countries this is forbidden. 533 (See Section 15.3.3).<br />

Provided that the objectives set out in this Directive are achieved, Member States<br />

may transpose the provisions on producer responsibility by means <strong>of</strong> voluntary<br />

agreements between the competent authorities and economic operators concerned.<br />

Article 27 stipulates the requirements these voluntary agreements should meet the<br />

following conditions:<br />

� They shall be enforceable;<br />

� They must specify objectives with corresponding deadlines;<br />

� They must be published in the national <strong>of</strong>ficial journal and transmitted to the<br />

Commission;<br />

� The results achieved must be monitored regularly, and reported to the<br />

competent authorities and the Commission, and made available to the public<br />

under the conditions set out in the agreement;<br />

533 Arcadis/Eunomia (2008) Optimising Markets for Recycling, Final Report to DG Environment,<br />

European Commission.


459<br />

� The competent authorities shall ensure that the progress made under such<br />

agreements is examined; and<br />

� In cases <strong>of</strong> non-compliance with the agreements, Member States shall<br />

implement the relevant provisions <strong>of</strong> this Directive by legislative, regulatory or<br />

administrative measures.<br />

25.1.2 Non-EU Countries<br />

In North America policy has tended to focus on voluntary programmes and outright<br />

bans, while South America and parts <strong>of</strong> Asia have developed policy more in line with<br />

the EU. These other non-EU countries are described in more detail in the sections that<br />

follow, though little market information is available.<br />

25.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

As mentioned above, producer responsibility policies covering batteries are in place in<br />

the EU and further afield.<br />

25.2.1 Europe<br />

Like other European compliance directives <strong>of</strong> this kind, the Batteries Directive serves<br />

the dual purpose <strong>of</strong> promoting better quality <strong>of</strong> life through a cleaner environment,<br />

while improving the European economy by standardizing technical manufacturing and<br />

marketing practices among European member states. Producer responsibility policies<br />

have been required for batteries because the levels <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials contained<br />

within them have historically been substantial.<br />

In landfills heavy metals such as mercury, cadmium and lead have the potential to<br />

leach into soil, groundwater or surface water and when incinerated, some heavy<br />

metals such as mercury may vaporise and escape into the air, while cadmium and<br />

lead may typically remain in bottom ash. It is estimated that in 2002 46% <strong>of</strong> portable<br />

batteries sold in the EU 15 that year were disposed <strong>of</strong> in landfill or incinerated. 534<br />

Cadmium is a toxic and carcinogenic substance. The <strong>International</strong> Agency for<br />

Research on Cancer has identified cadmium as a known human carcinogen. Mercury<br />

is known for a variety <strong>of</strong> documented, significant adverse impacts on human health<br />

and the environment. Mercury and its compounds are highly toxic, especially to the<br />

developing nervous system. The Swedish Government has recently announced that it<br />

will introduce a blanket ban on mercury, meaning that no products containing<br />

mercury may be placed on the Swedish market from June 2009. Lead is toxic to<br />

humans above certain concentrations and continued or acute over exposure can<br />

cause severe and cumulative health problems. 535<br />

534 Bio Intelligence Service (2003) Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong> Options for Revision <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Battery Directive, Final Report for EC, July 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/eia_batteries_final.pdf<br />

535 EC (2003) Directive <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council on Batteries and Accumulators<br />

and Spent Batteries and Accumulators – Extended Impact Assessment, Commission Staff Working<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Cadmium was, until recently, a component <strong>of</strong> one <strong>of</strong> the most widely used<br />

rechargeable batteries and according to the Commission proposal itself, 75% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

2,638 tonnes cadmium used in the EU-15 are incorporated in batteries and<br />

accumulators. Of these 1,984 tons, between 75% and 80% are used in the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> portable nickel-cadmium (NiCd) batteries. This corresponds to<br />

quantities between 1,488 and 1,587 tonnes <strong>of</strong> cadmium.<br />

The Batteries Directive (2006/66/EC) repeals Directive 91/157/EEC on Batteries<br />

and Accumulators Containing Certain Dangerous Substances, which introduced a<br />

limited range <strong>of</strong> environmental and product design requirements. The previous<br />

Directive was somewhat weak because it only covered an estimated 7% <strong>of</strong> consumer<br />

batteries on the EU market. In the words <strong>of</strong> the Commission the original Directive<br />

“has not succeeded in controlling adequately the risks they [batteries] pose”. There<br />

was also heavy resistance from industry and it was acknowledged that more research<br />

on certain substances was needed before more complete regulations were issued.<br />

When the Directive was revised to cover a wider range <strong>of</strong> batteries, all actors in the<br />

waste management chain became involved, from producer to the consumer through<br />

to collectors and reprocessors, rather than affecting product design with substance<br />

bans that manufacturers claimed were unreasonable.<br />

Consultations to revisions <strong>of</strong> the first battery Directive started in 1997, giving all<br />

interested parties a voice in legislation and policy, especially in assessing the<br />

directive’s economic, environmental and social impact.<br />

The proposal for a new Batteries Directive was made by the European Commission on<br />

24 November 2003, covering all batteries (for environmental and trade reasons).<br />

Following negotiation, the new Directive was adopted on 6 September 2006 and<br />

came into force on 26 September 2006.<br />

All Member States were required to transpose the Directive into national law by 26<br />

September 2008. At the time <strong>of</strong> writing only nine have made the transposition;<br />

Austria, Estonia, Hungary, Ireland, Latvia, Malta, the Netherlands, Slovenia and Spain.<br />

Three other Member States (Lithuania, Poland, Finland) have partially transposed the<br />

Batteries Directive, and a warning from the EC that it will take infringement action<br />

against member states if they do not “rapidly implement” the revised Batteries<br />

Directive is likely to spur non-conforming countries into action.<br />

Another principal driver for the policy is the sheer volume <strong>of</strong> battery waste that is<br />

generated each year, the rate at which this has been growing in recent years and is<br />

predicted to continue to grow. The European Commission’s Extended Impact<br />

Assessment (COM(2003)723 final), (EIA)) which supported the proposal to introduce<br />

the new Batteries Directive, estimated that the consumer battery market in Western<br />

Europe 536 had grown by some 70%, in terms <strong>of</strong> units sold, between 1985 and<br />

Paper, November 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/exten_impact_assessment.pdf<br />

536 EU 15 plus Norway and Switzerland.<br />

460<br />

29/09/09


1995. 537 This proliferation is principally explained by the rapid growth <strong>of</strong> widely<br />

available, low cost consumer electrical goods, such as mobile phones, lap top<br />

computers and MP3 players. It is estimated that in the EU well over 1 million tonnes<br />

<strong>of</strong> batteries enter the market each year (Table 25-1). The global demand for batteries<br />

is projected to grow by more than 5% annually over the coming years, with the<br />

portable batteries market growing fastest. 538<br />

Table 25-1: Tonnage estimation <strong>of</strong> batteries placed on the market in the EU in 2002<br />

461<br />

Battery Battery Type Type Type<br />

Tonnage Tonnage placed placed on on market market in in 2002<br />

2002<br />

Portable 160,000<br />

Automotive 800,000<br />

Industrial 190,000<br />

TOTAL TOTAL<br />

1,150,000<br />

1,150,000<br />

Source: EC Press Release IP/03/1596 (2003), Batteries: Commission requires collection and<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> all batteries, November 2003.<br />

The extent to which portable batteries are separately collected (and by extension,<br />

waste prevented in terms <strong>of</strong> reduced amounts <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials to<br />

landfill/incineration) varies widely across battery types and between Member States.<br />

Differences between countries are explored more closely in section 25.2.2, but<br />

generally speaking the collection rates <strong>of</strong> portable batteries are low across Member<br />

States, while collection rates for industrial and automotive are considerably higher.<br />

Automotive battery recycling has been taking place in Europe for a long time due to<br />

the inherent value <strong>of</strong> lead, the principle material contained in these batteries. Until<br />

very recently metal prices have been extremely buoyant, with lead no exception (see<br />

Figure 25-1). As a consequence the economics have pushed collection rates<br />

extremely high. For example in the UK, which is typical <strong>of</strong> other EU Member States<br />

and beyond, collection rates are currently around 97%. 539 Given that approximately<br />

98% <strong>of</strong> industrial batteries consist <strong>of</strong> lead-acid batteries, the situation is almost<br />

identical. Nonetheless, lead prices are subject to fluctuations and as such the<br />

economic incentive to collect and recycle these batteries could also fluctuate. Very<br />

few Member States have taken specific measures to ensure a continued effective<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> these batteries. In Italy and Germany there is a deposit scheme for<br />

automotive batteries which would still guarantee their return. However, the actual<br />

collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> those batteries is still largely dependent on the lead price.<br />

537 Bio Intelligence Service (2003) Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong> Options for Revision <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Battery Directive, Final Report for EC, July 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/eia_batteries_final.pdf<br />

538 Ibid.<br />

539 Arcadis/Eunomia Report for the EC, Optimising Markets for Recycling, due to be published late<br />

2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


It should also be mentioned that a recent US Geological Survey study found lead acid<br />

battery consumption has been under-reported in the US by 24%, reducing collection<br />

rates to approximately 80%. 540<br />

The extremely low collections rates <strong>of</strong> portable batteries in most Member States (for<br />

example, around 3% in the UK at present, with the remainder disposed <strong>of</strong> in landfill or<br />

incinerated) when compared to other battery types has meant that in practice the<br />

Batteries Directive is fundamentally geared to address this particular issue. 541<br />

Figure 25-1: Lead Price Graph 2003-2008 (US$ per tonne)<br />

Source: London Metal Exchange http://www.lme.co.uk/lead_graphs.asp<br />

25.2.2 EU Specific Characteristics<br />

An important consideration is how developed existing (or baseline) battery<br />

infrastructure is across Member States, as this will clearly have an impact on the<br />

countries’ implementation <strong>of</strong> the Batteries Directive. Broadly speaking 3 categories <strong>of</strong><br />

countries can be distinguished: 542<br />

462<br />

� Countries where separate collection <strong>of</strong> portable batteries was well developed<br />

before the implementation <strong>of</strong> the new Directive – Austria, Belgium, Finland,<br />

the Netherlands, Germany and Sweden (45-85% <strong>of</strong> portable batteries<br />

available for collection are estimated to be collected according to countries);<br />

540 US Geological Survey (2006) Apparent Consumption vs. Total Consumption – A Lead-Acid Battery<br />

Case Study, D.R. Wilburn and D.A. Buckingham, 2006.<br />

http://pubs.usgs.gov/sir/2006/5155/sir20065155.pdf<br />

541 Arcadis/Eunomia Report for the EC, Optimising Markets for Recycling, due to be published late<br />

2008.<br />

542 Bio Intelligence Service (2003) Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong> Options for Revision <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Battery Directive, Final Report for EC, July 2003, p9.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/eia_batteries_final.pdf<br />

29/09/09


463<br />

� Countries where separate collection <strong>of</strong> NiCd batteries was well developed –<br />

Denmark and Norway (40-50% <strong>of</strong> spent NiCd batteries are collected).<br />

� Countries where separate collection was not developed (0-15% <strong>of</strong> portable<br />

batteries available for collection are estimated to be collected in these<br />

countries).<br />

25.2.3 Non-EU Countries<br />

There are, however, countries outside the EU that adopted similar measures, and<br />

these are evaluated in more detail in the following section.<br />

25.2.3.1 North America<br />

In the 1990s, as proposals were circulating in Europe to ban cadmium in batteries,<br />

several states in the US, including Minnesota and New Jersey, enacted manufacturer<br />

take-back requirements on NiCd rechargeable batteries. In 1994, as the state takeback<br />

requirements were being phased in, a producer responsibility organisation<br />

called the Rechargeable Battery Recycling Corporation (RBRC) was established by the<br />

rechargeable battery industry in response to a report by the Environmental Protection<br />

Agency that NiCd batteries were responsible for more than half the cadmium found in<br />

the municipal waste stream. In 2001 the RBRC began to accept all rechargeable<br />

batteries.<br />

At the time, the scheme, the first industry-wide voluntary take-back programme in the<br />

US and Canada, was hailed as a model <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility, though by 2000 it<br />

was apparent that it was completely failing to meet the original targets it had set. The<br />

RBRC anticipated collecting 14 million pounds <strong>of</strong> batteries per year by 2003, but by<br />

2005 only 5 million pounds were being collected, highlighting the lack <strong>of</strong> clout <strong>of</strong> what<br />

was a ‘weak’ voluntary system. 543<br />

The US Congress did pass the Mercury-Containing and Rechargeable Battery Act in<br />

1996 and for these regulated batteries, the act requires the following:<br />

� Batteries must be easily removable from consumer products, to make it easier<br />

to recover them for recycling;<br />

� Battery labels must include the battery chemistry, the recycling symbol, and a<br />

phrase indicating that the user must recycle or dispose <strong>of</strong> the battery properly;<br />

� National uniformity in collection, storage, and transport <strong>of</strong> certain batteries;<br />

and<br />

� Phase out the use <strong>of</strong> certain mercury-containing batteries.<br />

Following this, many states passed legislation prohibiting incineration and landfilling<br />

<strong>of</strong> mercury-based and lead acid batteries.<br />

543 http://www.rbrc.org/docs/ProgramOverview.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


25.2.3.2 South America<br />

Perhaps surprisingly, Brazil has developed a very progressive position on battery<br />

waste. The National Environment Council (Conselho National do Medio Ambiente -<br />

CONAMA) has, in 2008, replaced the country’s 1999 rules on the environmental<br />

management <strong>of</strong> batteries. There are considerable similarities to the European<br />

Directive – limits on cadmium and mercury in batteries broadly mirror the EU<br />

thresholds, manufacturers and importers are required to register with the Federal<br />

Technical Registry <strong>of</strong> Potentially Polluting Activities, and labelling requirements are<br />

comparable.<br />

In addition, manufacturers and importers have to present the national environment<br />

enforcement agency (IBAMA) with a report <strong>of</strong> the chemical composition <strong>of</strong> batteries<br />

issued by a laboratory accredited by the national technical standards institute<br />

(INMETRO). Furthermore, Article 17 <strong>of</strong> the Resolution says that IBAMA, “based on<br />

proven and reasoned facts, may request, following its own criteria, sample lots <strong>of</strong><br />

batteries, <strong>of</strong> any kind, produced or imported for marketing in the country” for pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

compliance with the heavy metal limits, utilizing labs that are a signatory <strong>of</strong> the<br />

<strong>International</strong> Laboratory Accreditation Cooperation accords. The costs <strong>of</strong> such tests<br />

are to be met by the manufacturer or importer.<br />

In addition, under Article 3, all national manufacturers and importers <strong>of</strong> batteries<br />

must present IBAMA with a waste management plan, defined as an “environmentally<br />

adequate set <strong>of</strong> procedures for the discard, segregation, collection, transport, receipt,<br />

storage, handling, recycling, reuse, treatment or final disposal”.<br />

Going even further, under Article 19, manufacturers and importers <strong>of</strong> batteries<br />

covered by the Resolution must conduct studies on substituting or further reducing<br />

“potentially hazardous toxic substances” contained in their batteries.<br />

Other countries in South America have taken steps to follow Brazil’s lead, namely<br />

Columbia, Argentina, Paraguay.<br />

25.2.3.3 Japan<br />

Since the early 1980s Japan became aware <strong>of</strong> the environmental pollution impacts <strong>of</strong><br />

waste batteries in landfill and incineration. The use <strong>of</strong> mercury in manganese<br />

batteries was stopped in 1991 and in the following year in alkaline batteries. This has<br />

enabled significant reductions to be made in the amount <strong>of</strong> mercury used in batteries<br />

sold in Japan.<br />

At the same time Japan has established a comprehensive separate collection system<br />

for batteries and associated recycling infrastructure. In fact, Japan imports mercury<br />

containing wastes from several nearby countries including Thailand and the<br />

Philippines. 544 Many municipal authorities now participate in the Liaison Meeting for<br />

the Amalgamated Treatment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Batteries.<br />

544 Law for the Promotion <strong>of</strong> Effective Utilization <strong>of</strong> Resources<br />

http://www.meti.go.jp/english/information/data/cReEffectLe.pdf<br />

464<br />

29/09/09


This has been possible under a broader policy for the Law for Promotion <strong>of</strong> Effective<br />

Utilisation <strong>of</strong> Resources which seeks to reduce the generation <strong>of</strong> waste and to<br />

contribute to the protection <strong>of</strong> the environment. This law became effective from April<br />

2001 with respect to batteries includes the following requirements:<br />

465<br />

� Collection <strong>of</strong> small secondary batteries;<br />

� Recycling <strong>of</strong> small secondary batteries including recycling efficiency targets;<br />

� Enlightenment and providing information for collection; and<br />

� Acceptance <strong>of</strong> small secondary batteries collected through municipalities by<br />

manufacturers under producer responsibility.<br />

25.2.3.4 South Korea<br />

In South Korea producer responsibility was extended to batteries (manganese,<br />

alkaline manganese and Ni-MH) in 2008. This is in part to do with the memorandum<br />

<strong>of</strong> understanding that Korea has signed with a number EU countries which promotes<br />

cooperation in the area <strong>of</strong> environmental protection through the exchange <strong>of</strong> human<br />

resources and information. As such, much <strong>of</strong> Korea’s environmental policy reflects<br />

that <strong>of</strong> the EU. This also reflects the prominent role <strong>of</strong> South Korean manufacturers in<br />

some EU markets, for example some WEEE categories.<br />

25.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Typically national government environmental and business departments are<br />

responsible for implementing such regulations, with environmental agencies usually<br />

acting as the regulator. This process usually involves significant consultation with<br />

industry and other affected parties.<br />

Producer responsibility policies in the EU impose an obligation on producers,<br />

depending on the amount they put on the market, which they can either discharge<br />

themselves or through a collective scheme <strong>of</strong> some sort, generally known as<br />

“compliance schemes”. This framework can be delivered by either a single scheme or<br />

a number <strong>of</strong> schemes (multiple-schemes), both <strong>of</strong> which would be monitored by<br />

regulators. In the UK multiple compliance schemes (around 40) set up to deal with<br />

WEEE have led to complications in terms <strong>of</strong> reconciling the data between these<br />

schemes and the regulator. Despite this the UK Government has opted to pursue a<br />

multiple compliance scheme for batteries, stating that it “envisages that a marketdriven<br />

system <strong>of</strong> this design will provide more flexibility for producers, giving them an<br />

element <strong>of</strong> choice and potentially resulting in their incurring lower costs”. 545<br />

Proponents <strong>of</strong> the single scheme claim that competition is possible via this route,<br />

provided that a suitable tendering process is used.<br />

545 http://www.letsrecycle.com/do/ecco.py/view_item?listid=37&listcatid=326&listitemid=10152<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Retailers selling batteries would also be affected as in many Member States takeback<br />

schemes are required at the point <strong>of</strong> sale. Municipalities are also involved in the<br />

collection process, as <strong>of</strong> course are consumers.<br />

25.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The EC commissioned a report entitled ‘Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Options for Revision <strong>of</strong> the Battery Directive’. 546 The purpose <strong>of</strong> the study was to<br />

perform an analysis <strong>of</strong> the economic, environmental and social impacts <strong>of</strong> different<br />

battery policy options. This report led to a Commission Staff Working Paper<br />

Environmental Impact Assessment. 547<br />

Evaluations have also been carried out by industry. For example the European Battery<br />

Recycling Association published a position paper on the economic and social aspects<br />

<strong>of</strong> collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> batteries. 548<br />

Similar studies have been carried out at a national level. For example in the UK the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs commissioned a study on life<br />

cycle assessment <strong>of</strong> battery waste management. 549 Those countries which have<br />

already established producer responsibility legislation for batteries routinely<br />

undertake annual reviews <strong>of</strong> the mechanisms in place.<br />

25.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

25.5.1 Environmental Cost<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> attempting to attach a monetised cost to the environmental benefit <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling waste portable batteries, the UK study referenced above looked at the<br />

environmental implications <strong>of</strong> increased levels <strong>of</strong> battery recycling in the UK. By<br />

combining the performance <strong>of</strong> the best scenario, in terms <strong>of</strong> the avoided air<br />

emissions per tonne <strong>of</strong> portable batteries recycled, with unit damage costs for air<br />

pollutants from the Methodex database it is possible to derive a per tonne external<br />

benefit for portable battery recycling (clearly, this is for a mix <strong>of</strong> such batteries). The<br />

benefits are <strong>of</strong> the order €330 - €657 per tonne <strong>of</strong> batteries recycled. Clearly the<br />

environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> reducing battery waste are potentially significant, and for<br />

546 BIO Intelligence Service (2003) Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong> Options for Revision <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Battery Directive, Final Report for EC, July 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/eia_batteries_final.pdf<br />

547 EC (2003) Directive <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council on Batteries and Accumulators<br />

and Spent Batteries and Accumulators – Extended Impact Assessment, Commission Staff Working<br />

Paper, November 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/exten_impact_assessment.pdf<br />

548 Economic and social aspects related to the collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> used general purpose<br />

batteries, EBRA, September 2003. http://www.ebrarecycling.org/<br />

549 Defra (2006) Battery <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Life Cycle Assessment, Final report for publication,<br />

October 2006. http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/waste/topics/batteries/pdf/ermlcareport0610.pdf<br />

466<br />

29/09/09


specific battery types, they might exceed the estimate made here (which, in any case,<br />

majors on greenhouse gas and air pollution consequences – some <strong>of</strong> the effects are<br />

likely to be in reduced hazards <strong>of</strong> disposal which are more difficult to capture in a<br />

basic analysis).<br />

The next section highlights some analyses which look at the general environmental<br />

benefits <strong>of</strong> the removal <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances and increased recycling. Taking the<br />

performance in terms <strong>of</strong> collection and recycling as a proxy for environmental<br />

performance, we then review the factors which seem influential in driving<br />

improvements in collection rates.<br />

25.5.2 Environmental Consequences <strong>of</strong> Producer Responsibility for<br />

Batteries<br />

Several <strong>of</strong> the reports mentioned in previous sections have commented on the<br />

environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> battery collections.<br />

The Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong> Options for Revision <strong>of</strong> the Battery<br />

Directive states the relatively obvious – that the establishment <strong>of</strong> separate collection<br />

targets are expected to have positive consequences in terms <strong>of</strong> controls on the<br />

hazardous substances contained within batteries and also in the use <strong>of</strong> recycled<br />

rather than virgin materials (though these positive benefits may be partially <strong>of</strong>fset by<br />

the environmental impacts due to additional activities required to separate, collect<br />

and recycle batteries). 550 It should be noted however that transport logistics are not,<br />

usually, a decisive factor in determining impacts in environmental terms, especially,<br />

as here, when the external benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling are potentially so high.<br />

While a lack <strong>of</strong> LCA data meant that it was not possible to assess the overall<br />

environmental balance <strong>of</strong> collecting and recycling all portable batteries, an<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> NiCd batteries showed that there would be environmental benefits 2.5<br />

to 13 times higher than the baseline scenario. Whilst this is a wide range, since<br />

cadmium batteries are classified as hazardous waste and its substitutes (Nickel-<br />

Metal Hydride and Lithium chemistries) are not, one can conclude that the phasing<br />

out <strong>of</strong> cadmium batteries would result in decreased environmental impacts in the<br />

future.<br />

The same study estimates the amount <strong>of</strong> metals which could be recovered from<br />

portable batteries annually across the EU at 66,028 tonnes, the breakdown <strong>of</strong> which<br />

is shown in Table 19-2. It should be noted that these figures are based on portable<br />

battery sales information from 2002 and as such the levels <strong>of</strong> the hazardous<br />

substance cadmium are relatively high. With the tight restrictions on the use <strong>of</strong><br />

cadmium put forward in the Directive, and the banning <strong>of</strong> NiCd batteries in all but a<br />

few applications, there has been a significant reduction in the amount <strong>of</strong> cadmium<br />

being used in portable battery production for the EU market in recent years. For<br />

example, in Germany, from 2003 to 2007, the quantity in tonnage terms <strong>of</strong> NiCd<br />

550 BIO Intelligence Service (2003).<br />

467<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


atteries placed on the market fell by 64%. 551 This trend is likely to be followed<br />

internationally due to the size <strong>of</strong> the European market relative to the global market.<br />

In addition to the obvious benefit in reduction <strong>of</strong> cadmium use as a hazardous<br />

material (see Section 25.2.1), research suggests that the replacement <strong>of</strong> NiCd<br />

batteries by Nickel-Metal Hydride and Lithium batteries would result in decreased<br />

negative environmental impacts. In the case <strong>of</strong> complete replacement <strong>of</strong> NiCd<br />

batteries by these alternative chemistries, the lithosphere extraction indicator (LEI 552 )<br />

would decrease by 31%. 553<br />

In addition to the recoverable metals shown in Table 25-2, a range <strong>of</strong> substances<br />

such as various acids, salts and plastics can be captured by the recovery process and<br />

prevented from entering the waste stream.<br />

As would be expected the use <strong>of</strong> these secondary metals in battery production in<br />

place <strong>of</strong> virgin metals has environmental benefits as a result <strong>of</strong> reduced energy use<br />

and pollution related to the mining <strong>of</strong> virgin natural resources. For example, using<br />

recycled cadmium and nickel requires 46% and 75% less primary energy respectively,<br />

compared with the mining and refining <strong>of</strong> virgin sources. 554 These figures are<br />

particularly important in the context <strong>of</strong> primary metal production accounting for<br />

approximately 10% <strong>of</strong> global C02 emissions.<br />

Table 25-2: Annual Tonnages <strong>of</strong> Metals Recoverable in the EU<br />

468<br />

29/09/09<br />

Metal Metal<br />

Recoverable Recoverable Quantity Quantity (tonnes/year)<br />

(tonnes/year)<br />

Manganese 20,000<br />

Zinc 20,000<br />

Iron 15,000<br />

Lead 7,500<br />

Nickel 2,000<br />

Cadmium 1,500<br />

Mercury 28<br />

Source: EC (2003), Directive <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council on Batteries and<br />

Accumulators and Spent Batteries and Accumulators – Extended Impact Assessment, Commission<br />

Staff Working Paper, November 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/exten_impact_assessment.pdf<br />

551 Erfolgskontrolle GRS 2007.<br />

552 Ratio <strong>of</strong> anthropogenic to natural metal flows and the significance <strong>of</strong> battery production related to<br />

global metal mining.<br />

553 C.J. Rydh, B. Svärd (2002) Impact on global metal flows arising from the use <strong>of</strong> portable<br />

rechargeable batteries, The Science <strong>of</strong> the Total Environment, Vol. 302, No. 1-3.<br />

554 C.J. Rydh, M. Karlström (2002) Life Cyle Inventory <strong>of</strong> Recycling Portable Nickel-Cadmium Batteries,<br />

Resources, Conservation and Recycling.


For automotive and industrial batteries the higher the collection targets, the lower the<br />

environmental damages due to transport (recycling benefits increase more than<br />

transport negative impacts). The total environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> a ban on landfill for<br />

automotive and industrial batteries are difficult to quantify since the heavy metal<br />

content <strong>of</strong> leachate is difficult to predict on the basis <strong>of</strong> current knowledge.<br />

Furthermore, as stated above, recycling rates for automotive batteries are already<br />

high.<br />

25.6 Collection Performance and Key Drivers<br />

It is at this point interesting to consider the relative success <strong>of</strong> different approaches<br />

to the collection <strong>of</strong> portable batteries.<br />

Until recently one <strong>of</strong> the problems when comparing collection rates across different<br />

countries has been the method <strong>of</strong> calculation for this indicator. Various collection rate<br />

methodologies have been used, including as a percentage <strong>of</strong> sales, percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

spent batteries, and as a percentage <strong>of</strong> spent batteries available for collection. These<br />

three different methodologies lead to quite different ‘collection rates’ and so it is<br />

important to understand what is actually being reported by a particular country to<br />

avoid misleading claims. Table 25-3 provides a summary <strong>of</strong> the leading portable<br />

battery collectors in the EU, showing collection rates as a percentage <strong>of</strong> sales and so<br />

all countries are benchmarked evenly.<br />

Table 25-3: Leading EU Portable Battery Collection Performance in 2002<br />

469<br />

Country Country<br />

Belgium Belgium<br />

France France<br />

Germany Germany Netherland Netherlands<br />

Netherland<br />

Association BEBAT SCRELEC GRS STIBAT<br />

Starting Date 1996 2001 1998 1995<br />

Collection System<br />

Inhabitants per<br />

Collection Point<br />

Bring back –<br />

different types<br />

<strong>of</strong> collection<br />

points<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Bring back –<br />

point <strong>of</strong> sale and<br />

municipal<br />

collection points<br />

Bring back –<br />

predominately<br />

point <strong>of</strong> sale<br />

Bring back<br />

system with<br />

small chemical<br />

waste<br />

500 2,000 - 2,500 410 1,500<br />

Tonnes Collected 2,368 4,139 11,256 1,876<br />

Collection Rate (% <strong>of</strong><br />

sales)<br />

60% 16% 38% 32%<br />

Grams/inhabitant/year 228 69 137 116<br />

Source: BIO Intelligence Service (2003), Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong> Options for Revision <strong>of</strong><br />

the Battery Directive, Final Report for EC, July 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/eia_batteries_final.pdf<br />

Looking at Table 25-3 it can be seen that all countries have very similar collection<br />

systems in place - consumer bring back collection points <strong>of</strong> various types. Whilst it is


not possible to evaluate different types <strong>of</strong> collection systems, there are some<br />

interesting drivers <strong>of</strong> good performance represented here.<br />

The collection rate in Belgium is significantly higher than in other countries. This<br />

would seem in part to be explained by the relatively low number <strong>of</strong> inhabitants per<br />

collection point which is an indicator <strong>of</strong> scheme convenience, which tends to lead to<br />

higher participation (the Irish system is based upon similar high density approaches).<br />

Germany has a very similar number <strong>of</strong> inhabitants per collection point and has the<br />

second highest collection rate <strong>of</strong> the four countries in Table 25-3.<br />

Other reasons contributing to Belgium’s success rate include the fact that the<br />

national battery association BEBAT has been in place for some time (since 1996) and<br />

that more money has been spent on publicity and communications than in any <strong>of</strong> the<br />

other three countries. Linked to this is the fact that a unique way was being used<br />

(though this has since been replicated in Italy and Denmark) in Belgium to finance<br />

waste portable battery treatment. A 1996 law exempted batteries from what was<br />

effectively an environmental tax (€0.50 + VAT per battery) if a return system was<br />

established for the collecting and recycling <strong>of</strong> portable batteries. This exemption<br />

required specific collection targets to be met (65% by 2004). Funding was met by a<br />

€0.1239 + VAT per battery charge to be paid by the consumer (see Section 15.3.3).<br />

This means that not only is the Belgian system is very well funded, but there are also<br />

high statutory collection targets to meet.<br />

A recent comprehensive portable battery collection trial in the UK 555 is worth<br />

analysing because it compares a wide range <strong>of</strong> collection methods. The <strong>Waste</strong> and<br />

Resources Action Programme (WRAP) sought to examine the most cost effective way<br />

<strong>of</strong> collecting batteries to meet the targets under the forthcoming Directive. The trials<br />

involved assessing a variety <strong>of</strong> collection methods including kerbside collection,<br />

retailer banks, community drop-<strong>of</strong>f and postal return. These trials ran from April 2005<br />

to March 2008.<br />

25.6.1.1 Kerbside Schemes<br />

In the second year <strong>of</strong> the trial 12 kerbside collection trials were running across the<br />

UK, servicing approximately 444,000 households in a mixture <strong>of</strong> high-rise, urban and<br />

rural areas. Householders in the trial areas receive a dedicated collection container<br />

for their batteries (either sealable bags or a small cardboard box). This was set out<br />

with other kerbside materials on the appropriate day <strong>of</strong> collection (frequency <strong>of</strong><br />

collection varies from weekly to quarterly). There was a huge variation between the<br />

tonnages collected per household across individual kerbside schemes due to the<br />

different scheme features as well as the local characteristics <strong>of</strong> areas served. Overall,<br />

the kerbside systems delivered 0.127kg per household in the second year <strong>of</strong> the<br />

trials.<br />

555 WRAP (2008) Household Battery Collection Trials: April 2005 – March 2008, Final Report,<br />

November 2008. http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/Batteries_report_-_final.c6d1d62e.6153.pdf<br />

470<br />

29/09/09


25.6.1.2 Retailer Take-back Schemes<br />

This trial involved 33 major retail stores across three municipal areas serving<br />

approximately 200,000 households. Battery containers were installed in participating<br />

stores and shoppers can drop-<strong>of</strong>f all their used portable batteries. During the second<br />

year <strong>of</strong> the trial 0.043kg per household were collected.<br />

25.6.1.3 Community Drop-<strong>of</strong>f Schemes<br />

In this scheme householders were able to deposit portable batteries in containers<br />

located across the municipal area (on-street, public buildings, sport centres and local<br />

shops). Again the trial ran across three municipal areas in the second year, serving a<br />

total <strong>of</strong> 221,000 households. This resulted in 0.026kg per household being collected.<br />

25.6.1.4 Postal Scheme<br />

Targeted at rural areas this scheme supplied strong polythene pre-paid envelopes<br />

into which unwanted batteries could be placed. 38,000 households were served by<br />

the scheme, leading to 0.072kg per household being recovered.<br />

25.6.1.5 Comparisons<br />

Firstly it is worth highlighting that these trials were carried out in a near vacuum <strong>of</strong><br />

publicity and so tonnages collected are likely to be considerably higher when<br />

combined with a well funded, coordinated promotion. It is therefore not so much the<br />

actual figures that are <strong>of</strong> interest, but more the relative performance <strong>of</strong> these various<br />

schemes.<br />

From these results it can be seen that the kerbside schemes comfortably collected<br />

the most batteries per household served, capturing almost twice the amount <strong>of</strong> the<br />

postal scheme, three times more than the retailer take-back schemes and five times<br />

more than the community drop-<strong>of</strong>f schemes. This is likely to be attributable to the<br />

convenience factor <strong>of</strong> a kerbside collection, which is already well developed in the UK<br />

for a range <strong>of</strong> dry recyclables.<br />

The postal scheme, perhaps surprisingly, was the next most successful. This may be<br />

explained by the fact that all 38,000 households covered by the trial were sent prepaid<br />

envelopes which, as well as scoring relatively highly in convenience terms, would<br />

have also acted as prompt to householders.<br />

The retailer take-back and community drop-<strong>of</strong>f schemes collected the least portable<br />

batteries in per household terms. It would appear that the public preferred to deposit<br />

unwanted batteries at major retail outlets than community sites, despite a higher<br />

number <strong>of</strong> collection banks per capita at the latter. It could be argued that these<br />

schemes suffered more from a lack <strong>of</strong> direct engagement than the other schemes.<br />

25.7 Implementation Costs<br />

Indicative costs for collection and recycling across existing bring back collection<br />

schemes are shown in Table 25-4. Whilst this data is slightly dated (2002), it does<br />

show that the most significant costs involved are for the transport and recycling<br />

element.<br />

471<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


In an attempt to add a higher degree <strong>of</strong> resolution to the broad cost ranges shown in<br />

Table 25-4, the collection trials undertaken in the UK by WRAP can be examined. Due<br />

to the very nature <strong>of</strong> these trial schemes, coverage in many places was only a few<br />

thousand households, and thus, economies <strong>of</strong> scale were not achieved. WRAP was<br />

also keen to be able to monitor individual scheme performance to allow a thorough<br />

evaluation. This meant that a premium was paid for collection and reprocessing (the<br />

WRAP report suggests a cost reduction in the order <strong>of</strong> 40-50% would be possible if<br />

schemes were rolled out nationally). As for the tonnage performance already<br />

discussed the trial costs per tonne shown should not be viewed as indicative <strong>of</strong> a<br />

widespread national programme, but these costs are interesting from a relative<br />

perspective.<br />

Table 25-4: Cost Ranges for Existing Portable Battery Bring Back Collection Schemes<br />

472<br />

29/09/09<br />

Variable Variable Costs: Costs:<br />

Euros/tonne Euros/tonne <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> portable portable batteries batteries collected<br />

collected<br />

Collection points (equipment) 50-150<br />

Collection (logistics) 250-550<br />

Sorting 150-250<br />

Transport and Recycling (excluding disposal) 400-900<br />

Fixed Fixed Fixed Costs:<br />

Costs:<br />

Public Relations and communication 50-1,700<br />

Administration 125-900<br />

TOTAL TOTAL<br />

1,115 1,115 – 3,765<br />

3,765<br />

Source: BIO Intelligence Service (2003), Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong> Options for Revision <strong>of</strong><br />

the Battery Directive, Final Report for EC, July 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/eia_batteries_final.pdf<br />

Table 25-5 shows that kerbside collections run by third sector organisations were the<br />

most expensive <strong>of</strong> the WRAP collection trial schemes and more than four times more<br />

expensive than municipal kerbside collection. WRAP suggest the reason for this<br />

significant difference is due to the terms <strong>of</strong> existing contracts with collection<br />

organisations that municipalities enjoy (i.e. some <strong>of</strong> these costs can be absorbed<br />

within the existing working day so that the new costs are marginal ones rather then<br />

being wholly additional).<br />

This explanation is supported by a kerbside recycling collection company in the UK<br />

(May Gurney) that collects portable batteries as part <strong>of</strong> its contracted services to<br />

municipalities. Due to the relatively small amounts <strong>of</strong> portable batteries collected, the<br />

net additional cost <strong>of</strong> collecting this material alongside a range <strong>of</strong> others is quite<br />

negligible, whilst reprocessing costs are <strong>of</strong>fset by the income the contractor receives<br />

from reprocessors for automotive batteries also collected from the kerbside. The<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> this cost <strong>of</strong>fsetting is, <strong>of</strong> course, dependant on the state <strong>of</strong> market.


Table 25-5: Average Cost per Kilogramme <strong>of</strong> Portable Batteries Collected and<br />

Recycled<br />

Collection Collection Scheme<br />

Kerbside<br />

Kerbside<br />

(Community)<br />

(Community)<br />

Kerbside<br />

Kerbside<br />

(Mu (Municipal) (Mu nicipal)<br />

473<br />

Total Total Cost Cost £ £<br />

£<br />

(ongoing (ongoing (ongoing and and and set<br />

set<br />

up) up)<br />

up)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Tonnes Tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Batteries<br />

Batteries<br />

Collected<br />

Collected<br />

Average Average Cost Cost per<br />

per<br />

Tonne Tonne <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Batteries<br />

Batteries<br />

Collected Collected and<br />

and<br />

Recycled Recycled (£/tonne)<br />

(£/tonne)<br />

Estimated<br />

Estimated<br />

Cost Cost Cost ( (-45%) ( ( 45%)<br />

for for National<br />

National<br />

Roll Roll-out Roll out<br />

(£/tonne)<br />

(£/tonne)<br />

208,297 12.67 16,440 9,042<br />

169,051 43.87 3,853 2,119<br />

Retailer Retailer Take Take-back Take back 83,653 8.5 9,842 5,413<br />

Community Community Community Drop-<br />

Drop<br />

<strong>of</strong>f<br />

<strong>of</strong>f<br />

55,210 5.74 9,618 5,290<br />

Postal Postal<br />

43,487 2.72 15,988 8,793<br />

Postal scheme costs are almost as expensive as the community sector collections,<br />

namely due to the significant costs associated with production and distribution <strong>of</strong><br />

robust envelopes and the pre-paid postage <strong>of</strong> returns.<br />

The retailer take back and community drop-<strong>of</strong>f costs are almost identical as the<br />

schemes are very similar in nature. Relative to the other forms <strong>of</strong> collection, their<br />

costs per tonne fall between municipal kerbside collections and community sector<br />

kerbside / postal.<br />

One area the UK can make further cost improvements to bring back portable battery<br />

schemes is in the area <strong>of</strong> reverse-logistics, particularly from large retail outlets that<br />

have substantial transport infrastructure in place. Not only will cost savings be made<br />

but the environmental benefits associated with recycling waste batteries will increase<br />

as collection rounds become more efficient, with shorter distances per pick up.<br />

25.8 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Batteries can be divided into two families: primary and secondary. Primary batteries<br />

are designed to be used only once, whereas secondary batteries are rechargeable.<br />

Product innovation has led to significant battery advancements in recent years,<br />

particularly in respect <strong>of</strong> lithium-ion batteries. These secondary batteries are<br />

increasingly used in consumer electronics, replacing the more traditional chemistries<br />

such as NiCd. Their principal advantage is an extremely high energy-to-weight ratio,<br />

though they also experience little memory effect and a slow loss <strong>of</strong> charge when not<br />

in use. As a result <strong>of</strong> these key attributes and environmental considerations, NiCd<br />

batteries have more or less been consigned to history.<br />

An even more recent development is the silver-zinc battery, which it has been claimed<br />

will provide 40% more power than a lithium-ion battery <strong>of</strong> the same size. Those<br />

developing this new rechargeable battery chemistry claim it will be 95% recyclable by


weight and contain no heavy metals or toxic chemicals (though silver is regulated as<br />

hazardous waste by the US Environmental Protection Agency). It is expected that<br />

silver-zinc batteries will start to be used in laptop computer manufacturing from mid-<br />

2009.<br />

In the developed world, manufacturers are producing more secondary batteries each<br />

year relative to the number <strong>of</strong> primary batteries produced. For example, the National<br />

Electrical Manufacturers Association has estimated that US demand for secondary<br />

batteries is growing twice as fast as demand for single use batteries. 556 The<br />

increased demand for personal consumer electronics is the principal cause <strong>of</strong> this<br />

trend, rather than public awareness <strong>of</strong> environmental issues leading to switches<br />

across battery types.<br />

Industry has commented that improvements can be made to existing processing<br />

technologies, and these will be driven by further research and development on the<br />

back <strong>of</strong> the Directive efficiency targets, the greater volumes <strong>of</strong> batteries requiring<br />

recycling, and increased competition. At times when the price <strong>of</strong> metals is high, this<br />

will also tend to encourage a greater separation <strong>of</strong> materials and a drive for higher<br />

levels <strong>of</strong> purity.<br />

H J Enthoven & Sons, as the only lead acid battery reprocessor in the UK, noted, that<br />

improvements in battery technology continue to lead to reduced battery weights, and<br />

so this can be expected to have an impact on the growth rate <strong>of</strong> industrial battery<br />

wastes, expressed in tonnage terms.<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> Mechanical Biological Treatment (MBT) plants now exist across Europe<br />

and this number is expecting to grow considerably in the future as Landfill Directive<br />

targets become increasingly challenging. Some <strong>of</strong> these are being designed with pretreatment<br />

specified in such a way (for example, using x-ray technology) that would<br />

allow the batteries to be separated from the residual waste at an early stage in the<br />

process.<br />

25.9 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

Due to the current high collection rates across Europe for automotive and industrial<br />

batteries there is unlikely to be any discernable price change in these battery types as<br />

a result <strong>of</strong> the Directive.<br />

Annual household expenditure on portable batteries is low (in the UK the average<br />

household uses 21 portable batteries per annum) as a proportion <strong>of</strong> overall spending<br />

so any producer responsibility costs reflected in pricing are unlikely to have an<br />

adverse effect on low-income households in a significant way. 557 In Belgium<br />

collection and recycling schemes are funded by a 0.1239 EUR + VAT per battery tax<br />

charged to the consumer, a tax which has not caused social unrest. Supposing similar<br />

usage figures to the UK, the suggestion is that a high collection rate scheme can<br />

556 http://www.epa.gov/osw/partnerships/stewardship/products/batteries.htm<br />

557 WRAP, Battery Facts & Figures<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/local_authorities/batteries/battery_recycling_information/battery_facts_.html<br />

474<br />

29/09/09


effectively be financed at a cost <strong>of</strong> around €2.5 per household per year. Few<br />

households would be expected to notice this in their budgeting.<br />

The increased level <strong>of</strong> regulation, the need for additional collection/recycling and the<br />

research and development required to deliver altered/new battery chemistries is<br />

likely to lead to a widening <strong>of</strong> employment opportunities. Bio Intelligence calculated<br />

the potential job creation opportunities in the EU for different collection rates. These<br />

are shown in Table 25-6.<br />

Table 25-6: Estimation <strong>of</strong> Job Creation with Portable Battery Collection Rates across<br />

the EU<br />

Collection<br />

Collection<br />

Rate Rate (%<br />

(%<br />

annual<br />

annual<br />

sales)<br />

sales)<br />

Tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

batteries<br />

collected<br />

(‘000s)<br />

Total<br />

Jobs<br />

Created<br />

475<br />

10 10- 10<br />

20%<br />

20%<br />

1,238-<br />

1,444<br />

20 20- 20<br />

30%<br />

30%<br />

30 30- 30<br />

40%<br />

40%<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

40 40- 40<br />

50%<br />

50%<br />

50 50- 50<br />

60%<br />

60%<br />

60 60- 60<br />

70%<br />

70%<br />

70 70- 70<br />

80%<br />

80%<br />

80 80- 80<br />

90%<br />

90%<br />

90 90- 90<br />

100%<br />

100%<br />

25 41 58 74 91 107 125 140 157<br />

2,063-<br />

2,406<br />

2,888-<br />

3,369<br />

3,713-<br />

4,331<br />

4,538-<br />

5,294<br />

5,363-<br />

6,256<br />

6,188-<br />

7,219<br />

7,013-<br />

8,181<br />

7,838-<br />

9,144<br />

Source: BIO Intelligence Service (2003), Impact Assessment on Selected <strong>Policy</strong> Options for Revision <strong>of</strong><br />

the Battery Directive, Final Report for EC, July 2003.<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/waste/batteries/pdf/eia_batteries_final.pdf<br />

25.10 Complementary Policies<br />

Directive (2002/96/EC) on <strong>Waste</strong> Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE) has<br />

been implemented with the purpose <strong>of</strong>, preventing WEEE, and in addition the re-use,<br />

recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> WEEE, thereby reducing the need for its disposal. As many<br />

items <strong>of</strong> WEEE contain batteries, there are clearly policy inter-linkages. Indeed<br />

clarifying responsibilities for WEEE producers who are also battery producers is one <strong>of</strong><br />

the key issues facing Member States as they implement the Battery Directive.<br />

Directive 2002/95/EC on the Restriction <strong>of</strong> Hazardous Substances (RoHS) must also<br />

be considered as a policy driver alongside producer responsibility for batteries in the<br />

EU; the RoHS Directive aims to minimise the use <strong>of</strong> certain hazardous materials in<br />

newly-produced EEE and to minimise the release <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances into the<br />

environment by controlling the disposal route <strong>of</strong> older equipment at the end <strong>of</strong> its life.<br />

Producers must provide evidence that the concentrations <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials are<br />

below defined levels. The six key restricted substances are lead, cadmium, mercury,<br />

hexavalent chromium, polybrominated biphenyls and polybrominated diphenyl.<br />

The Energy-Using Products (EuP) Directive 2005/32/EC, which came into force in<br />

August 2007, provides a framework for the setting <strong>of</strong> eco-design requirements for any<br />

group <strong>of</strong> products which use energy (including EEE). This directive seeks to make<br />

energy efficiency improvements rather than having a direct focus on waste. However,<br />

ensuing product designs which make energy efficiency improvements may also<br />

extend the product’s life, thus contributing indirectly to the prevention <strong>of</strong> WEEE.


Directive 2000/53/EC on End <strong>of</strong> Life Vehicles (ELV) aims to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

waste from vehicles when they are finally scrapped. It also sets higher reuse, recycling<br />

and recovery targets and limits the use <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances in both new vehicles<br />

and replacement vehicle parts. This Directive therefore has a direct impact on the<br />

automotive battery industry.<br />

25.11 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The policy is intended to reflect the relative environmental performance in the price <strong>of</strong><br />

the product, e.g. secondary (recyclable) batteries will be cheaper. Higher cost will be<br />

attached to the more polluting products.<br />

Belgium has achieved high collection rates through a 1996 law that exempted<br />

batteries from what was effectively an environmental tax (€0.50 + VAT per battery) if<br />

a return system was established for the collecting and recycling <strong>of</strong> portable batteries.<br />

Funding was met by a €0.1239 + VAT per battery charge to be paid by the consumer.<br />

Whilst substitutes for portable NiCd batteries are developing rapidly (see section<br />

25.8), these replacement chemistries are generally more expensive at the current<br />

time. Some attempts have been made to estimate these additional costs, but given<br />

the speed <strong>of</strong> technological advancement in this area it is inherently difficult to <strong>of</strong>fer a<br />

cost that is not either a broad range, or one that becomes outdated extremely quickly.<br />

25.12 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Substantial enforcement will be required in order to create a level playing field for<br />

battery manufacturers and reprocessors. There is concern within the industry <strong>of</strong><br />

illegal practice and this is likely to intensify as more players enter the market as<br />

Member States strive for higher targets.<br />

G&P Batteries, a battery collector and reprocessor in the UK, carried out research into<br />

the mercury content <strong>of</strong> portable alkaline batteries found on the UK domestic market.<br />

This analysis showed that a kilogram <strong>of</strong> European branded batteries fell well within<br />

the proposed legal limits <strong>of</strong> cadmium and mercury levels, though astonishingly a<br />

kilogram <strong>of</strong> batteries from the Far East revealed mercury levels <strong>of</strong> 255 ppm (The EU<br />

Batteries Directive prohibits levels >5ppm), as well as elevated levels <strong>of</strong> cadmium<br />

and benzene. These findings clearly show that for the Directive targets to be met, a<br />

greater consideration may need to be given to the control <strong>of</strong> batteries imported from<br />

countries where similar standards are not routinely applied.<br />

If illegal practices are not squeezed out <strong>of</strong> the system, not only will there be<br />

significant environmental risks, but the legitimate businesses will suffer as those<br />

operating illegally will be able to undercut their prices. Illegal practice is also likely to<br />

feedback to risk aversion from the market. National and international policing by<br />

regulators is therefore crucial to the long-term viability <strong>of</strong> the industry.<br />

25.13 Lessons Learned<br />

Producer responsibility as a voluntary measure has had limited success as the<br />

industry has protected its financial interests as far as possible. This has led to<br />

compulsory measures that are now starting to bite in Europe and beyond.<br />

476<br />

29/09/09


Collection methods in Europe have predominately focused on networks <strong>of</strong> bring back<br />

systems that become increasingly beneficial in cost and environmental terms as<br />

collection rates increase. Reprocessing costs for batteries remain high (with<br />

significant variation according to chemistry), though these may fall as the collected<br />

quantities grow in the face <strong>of</strong> statutory targets.<br />

Whilst the UK is yet to make its intentions clear in terms <strong>of</strong> a national collection<br />

infrastructure, experience there suggests that batteries can be efficiently collected as<br />

additions to existing kerbside networks though this may depend upon the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

the collection system used. Consumer awareness <strong>of</strong> the issues around battery waste<br />

is low throughout much <strong>of</strong> the world. This is the case despite the hazardous nature <strong>of</strong><br />

many batteries, which one might have expected to lead to a greater understanding <strong>of</strong><br />

the need to reduce and recycle. To overcome this knowledge gap, significant efforts<br />

will need to be made on publicity material to the general public, as their involvement<br />

will be crucial if battery collection targets are to be achieved.<br />

25.14 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

Producer responsibility is now widely accepted as a vital part <strong>of</strong> moving towards a<br />

green economy. For those countries who have introduced producer responsibility for<br />

portable batteries, this has tended to come as a ‘second phase’ <strong>of</strong> products after the<br />

initial establishment <strong>of</strong> the policy for packaging, WEEE and ELVs. This is not, however,<br />

a prerequisite and the Battery Directive is likely to shift European states to perceive<br />

batteries as a product requiring greater attention than, in many cases, they have<br />

achieved hitherto.<br />

477<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


26.0 Producer Responsibility, Batteries - Germany<br />

26.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

According to the Battery Decree (Batterieverordnung - BattV) all producers/importers<br />

and retailers are obliged to collect free <strong>of</strong> charge used portable batteries and<br />

accumulators <strong>of</strong> the kind they have sold. 558 Consumers are not allowed to dispose <strong>of</strong><br />

spent portable batteries in the residual waste and instead have to return them to<br />

retailers selling batteries, other retail collection points or local municipality collection<br />

points , e.g. town hall (Articles 5 and 15 BattV). Retailers have a duty to inform<br />

consumers <strong>of</strong> the possibilities to return batteries to the retailer (Articles 12 and 15<br />

BattV) and are required to take back used batteries regardless <strong>of</strong> whether these were<br />

purchased in their store. The producers/importers have to organize the recycling, or if<br />

not possible, the safe disposal <strong>of</strong> batteries. 559 The collection system has to guarantee<br />

the following conditions:<br />

478<br />

� Be available to all manufacturers under the same terms and conditions;<br />

� Collect all batteries, regardless <strong>of</strong> their type, brand or origin;<br />

� Collect batteries free <strong>of</strong> charge from the collection points agreed with the<br />

retailers or at the collection points provided by the municipalities, and proceed<br />

with recycling or disposal;<br />

� Provide suitable collection containers at the collection points free <strong>of</strong> charge;<br />

� Issue invitations to tender for collection and treatment/disposal services such<br />

as logistics, collection, transportation, sorting, battery recycling and the<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> non-recyclable batteries in a procedure which ensures a<br />

competitive allocation, for a maximum <strong>of</strong> three years;<br />

� Secure funding by ensuring that the costs remaining after collection, recycling<br />

and disposal, including sales tax and other necessary overheads, are divided<br />

among the individual manufacturers in proportion to the share <strong>of</strong> the<br />

respective previous year's sales (according to the volume <strong>of</strong> batteries<br />

subdivided by type), and that appropriate contributions are made by the<br />

individual manufacturers; and<br />

� Publish, at least once a year, the costs <strong>of</strong> collection, sorting, recycling and<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> the collected batteries, subdivided by type.<br />

558 Batterieverordnung (BattV) as <strong>of</strong>: 27 March 1998 (Federal Law Gazette BGBl. I, p. 658).<br />

559 A different regulation is in force for automotive batteries. To achieve a maximum return rate <strong>of</strong> used<br />

automotive batteries the consumer has to pay a compulsory deposit <strong>of</strong> 7.50 EUR when buying a new<br />

battery without returning a used battery in its place (Article 6 BattV).<br />

29/09/09


26.2 Reasons for the <strong>Policy</strong><br />

According to the German Government 33,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> portable batteries are sold in<br />

Germany each year, <strong>of</strong> which 85% are non-rechargeable batteries (primary) and 15%<br />

are rechargeable batteries (accumulators). 560 Until April 1998 the retailers in<br />

Germany were taking back batteries containing toxic substances according to a<br />

voluntary agreement. Due to the fact that under the voluntary agreement only one<br />

fifth <strong>of</strong> the sold batteries were collected, the “Federal Decree Regarding the Collection<br />

and Disposal <strong>of</strong> Used Batteries and Accumulators – BattV” was implemented in<br />

Germany transposing the EU Battery Directive.<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> the decree is to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances in waste<br />

batteries in the following manner:<br />

479<br />

� Batteries containing certain hazardous substances may not be put into<br />

circulation;<br />

� Used batteries are taken back and recycled safely and properly in accordance<br />

with the provisions <strong>of</strong> the German <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Recycling Act, or<br />

non-recyclable batteries are disposed <strong>of</strong> in a manner compatible with public<br />

health; and<br />

� Batteries should be manufactured in such a way to make them reusable and<br />

technically long-lasting.<br />

In its second programme on the reduction <strong>of</strong> environmental pollution caused by<br />

batteries, the German Government aimed at a collection rate <strong>of</strong> 60% by the end <strong>of</strong><br />

2006, 561 particularly through improved information to the public. 562<br />

The timetable for the introduction <strong>of</strong> the policy was as follows:<br />

� 18 th March 1991: EU Directive 91/157/EEC regarding batteries and<br />

accumulators containing hazardous substances; 563<br />

� Until 1998 in Germany: Voluntary agreement on the take back <strong>of</strong> batteries;<br />

� 27 th March 1998: German Battery Decree serves to implement the Council<br />

Directive 91/157/EEC the Commission Directive 93/86/EEC; 564<br />

560 EUWID from 06.005.2003, p. 17.<br />

561 Compare, the adapted collection quota according to the proposed new Battery regulation in<br />

Germany <strong>of</strong> only 35%, in Chapter 1.1.11.<br />

562 Programm der Bundesregierung zur Verminderung der Umweltbelastungen aus Batterien und<br />

Altbatterien entsprechend Art. 6 der Richtlinie 91/157/EWG über gefährliche St<strong>of</strong>fe enthaltene<br />

Batterien und Akkumulatoren, 30. April 2003.<br />

563 OJ EC No. L 78, p. 38.<br />

564 Commission Directive 93/86/EEC <strong>of</strong> 4 October 1993, by way <strong>of</strong> amendment <strong>of</strong> the Council<br />

Directive 91/157/EEC regarding batteries and accumulators containing hazardous substances in<br />

technical progress, OJ EC No. L 264 p. 51,<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


480<br />

� 1 st September 2001: Revision <strong>of</strong> the Battery Decree 565 transposing the<br />

Directive 98/101/EC 566 on the maximum mercury content <strong>of</strong> lead acid<br />

batteries (0.0005%); and<br />

� The transposition <strong>of</strong> the EU Directive 2006/66/EC 567 had not been completed<br />

in Germany at the time <strong>of</strong> writing.<br />

26.2.1.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

The collection and recycling system <strong>of</strong> the Gemeinsame Rücknahmesystem Batterien<br />

(GRS) for portable batteries operates throughout Germany, although, the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

batteries returned per capita differs significantly between states. Compared to the<br />

average portable battery collection rate <strong>of</strong> 171g per capita in 2007, the return rate in<br />

two <strong>of</strong> the eastern states <strong>of</strong> Germany was below 101g per capita, as Figure 26-1<br />

shows.<br />

Figure 26-1: Battery Collection in Germany 2007<br />

Source GRS, Annual <strong>Review</strong>/Documentation 2008<br />

565 First Decree amending the Battery Decree as from 26.06.2001, Federal Law Gazette BGBl. I,<br />

p. 1361.<br />

566 Commission Directive 98/101/EC dated 22 December 1998 by way <strong>of</strong> amendment to the Council<br />

Directive 91/157/EEC regarding batteries and accumulators containing hazardous substances in<br />

technical progress, OJ EC No. L 1 , p. 1.<br />

567 Directive 2006/66/EC <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> 6 September 2006 on<br />

batteries and accumulators and waste batteries and accumulators and repealing Directive<br />

91/157/EEC, OJ EC No. L 266, p. 1.<br />

29/09/09


26.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Manufacturers and retailers are only allowed to put portable batteries (including<br />

those incorporated into appliances) on the market if they ensure that the consumer<br />

can return the batteries free <strong>of</strong> charge (Article 3 BattV). To that aim the<br />

manufacturers must ensure the collection <strong>of</strong> used portable batteries by establishing a<br />

common collection and recycling system, or by participating in such a system. As a<br />

consequence the GRS was established, providing a fund for the uniform and nationwide<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> spent portable batteries in Germany. GRS was founded in May<br />

1998 by leading battery manufacturers and the German Electrical and Electronic<br />

Manufacturers' Association (ZVEI). The fund is financed by contributions from its<br />

users. Manufacturers and importers pay contributions to the foundation for the<br />

services rendered, through a trustee, and in accordance with the quantity and type <strong>of</strong><br />

batteries sold in Germany. At the end <strong>of</strong> 2007 901 producers and importers were<br />

members <strong>of</strong> the GRS, compared to only 432 members in the year 2000.<br />

In accordance with Article 10 <strong>of</strong> the Battery Decree, the GRS prepares a report by 31<br />

March every year, which includes information on:<br />

481<br />

� Batteries put into circulation, volume <strong>of</strong> batteries collected, sorting <strong>of</strong> spent<br />

portable batteries, recycling and disposal results;<br />

� Summary <strong>of</strong> the operating procedures;<br />

� Total prices paid for sorting, recycling and disposal;<br />

� Quality assurance and environmental protection; and<br />

� Public relations.<br />

Besides the GRS, other producers (e.g. producers <strong>of</strong> special batteries) have set up<br />

separate take-back systems, like the Bosch Recycling Centre for Accumulators in<br />

Electronic Tools (drilling machines etc) or the Organisation for Recycling <strong>of</strong> Secondary<br />

Materials (Vereinigung für Wertst<strong>of</strong>frecycling - VFW), which is empowered by many<br />

producers to collect and recycle their batteries.<br />

26.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The following evaluation studies have been undertaken:<br />

� GRS, Annual <strong>Review</strong>/Documentation 2007, Performance <strong>Review</strong> in<br />

accordance with the German Battery Decree, March 2008.<br />

� Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen (SRU) Umweltgutachten 2004, Mai<br />

2004, p. 564, see: http://www.umweltrat.de<br />

� BOSCH (2003): Recyclingzentrum Elektrowerkzeuge: Erfolgskontrolle 2002<br />

gemäß § 10 Batterieverordnung. Robert Bosch GmbH.<br />

� German Government (2003): 2. Programm der Bundesregierung zur<br />

Verminderung der Umweltbelastungen aus Batterien und Altbatterien<br />

entsprechend Artikel 6 der Richtlinie 91/157/EWG über gefährliche St<strong>of</strong>fe<br />

enthaltende Batterien und Akkumulatoren, see:<br />

http://www.bmu.de/files/zweite_programm.pdf [as from 06.04.2003].<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


482<br />

� GRS Batterien (2003): Erfolgskontrolle 2002. Hamburg: GRS Batterien, see:<br />

http://www.grs-batterien.de/facts/pict/erfolg02.pdf [as from 20.08.2003].<br />

� Vfw AG (2003): Vfw-REBAT. Erfolgskontrolle für das Jahr 2002 gemäß § 10<br />

Batterieverordnung. Köln. Not published.<br />

� BOSCH (2000): Recyclingzentrum Elektrowerkzeuge: Erfolgskontrolle 1999<br />

gemäß § 10 Batterieverordnung. Robert Bosch GmbH.<br />

� Vfw AG (2000): Vfw-REBAT. Erfolgskontrolle für das Jahr 1999 gemäß § 10<br />

Batterieverordnung. Köln. Not published.<br />

26.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

Concerning NiCd Batteries, the amount <strong>of</strong> batteries (including those in appliances)<br />

put on the market in Germany decreased from 1,967 tonnes in 2003 to<br />

approximately 1,253 tonnes in 2007. 568 In 2007 this equates to 4 % <strong>of</strong> the total<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> portable batteries put on the market in Germany. It seems quite unlikely<br />

that this decrease has been significantly influenced by the Battery Decree, as this<br />

<strong>of</strong>fers no incentives for consumers to change consumption habits. The decrease in<br />

market share <strong>of</strong> the NiCd batteries does appear to be due more to technological<br />

innovations, although producers may have been becoming more aware <strong>of</strong> the desire<br />

to see significant reductions in cadmium in batteries under the Batteries Directive.<br />

Experience in the UK, where not equivalent to the German Regulations were in place<br />

(refer to Section 25.0), seems to supports this.<br />

The waste stream in 2007 was composed <strong>of</strong> 82% primary batteries and 18%<br />

secondary batteries (see Figure 26-2). In 2007, as in the year before, almost 1.5<br />

billion portable batteries were put into circulation (33,000 tonnes). The collection<br />

rate achieved was 43% and the recycling rate achieved was 38% (see Figure 26-3). Of<br />

the 13,645 tonnes <strong>of</strong> portable batteries entering GRS sorting plants in 2007, 8%<br />

were disposed <strong>of</strong> (92% recycling efficiency) compared to 81% (19% recycling<br />

efficiency) in 1999 (see Figure 26-3). 569<br />

160,000 collection sites are run by the GRS, <strong>of</strong> which 140,000 are retail outlets. The<br />

data in Figure 26-3 shows that 47% <strong>of</strong> portable batteries collected by GRS came from<br />

collections at retail outlets, 23% from waste collection local authorities and 30% from<br />

industry. This shows that whilst retail take-back delivers the highest proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

portable batteries, the contributions from local authorities and industry are still<br />

significant.<br />

568 GRS 2003, 2002, 2001; BOSCH, 2003, 2000; VfW-REBAT, 2003, 2000, Erfolgskontrolle GRS<br />

2007.<br />

569 Data from GRS, Recycling Magazin from 6.10.2008, p. 12 (13).<br />

29/09/09


Figure 26-2: German Battery Composition Breakdown, 2007<br />

Source GRS, Annual <strong>Review</strong>/Documentation 2008<br />

Figure 26-3: German Portable Battery Collection Routes, 2007<br />

Source GRS, Annual <strong>Review</strong>/Documentation 2008.<br />

26.6 Implementation Costs<br />

According to the EU Battery Directive producers have to bear all net costs and as<br />

previously stated the GRS (and other similar schemes) is financed by contributions<br />

from its users.<br />

483<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


26.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Regarding the influence <strong>of</strong> the Battery Decree on the sales figures <strong>of</strong> rechargeable<br />

batteries, 22% <strong>of</strong> batteries put into circulation in 2007 were rechargeable (see Figure<br />

26-4). Although the number <strong>of</strong> rechargeable batteries in the sales figures has<br />

increased slightly since 2003, the Öko-Institut concludes that there has neither been<br />

a relevant shift <strong>of</strong> consumers to buy rechargeable batteries, nor is the increase<br />

attributable to the Battery Decree.<br />

Figure 26-4: Batteries in Circulation in Germany, 2007<br />

Source GRS, Annual <strong>Review</strong>/Documentation 2008.<br />

26.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

See Section 25.9.<br />

26.9 Complementary Policies<br />

See Section 25.10. In addition, one might argue that, regarding the share <strong>of</strong> 22%<br />

secondary batteries in the sales figures, complementary policies would be necessary<br />

to increase their share. Possible instruments to be considered should address the<br />

higher sales prices <strong>of</strong> secondary batteries compared to that <strong>of</strong> primary batteries. Such<br />

policies are not in place in Germany.<br />

26.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

It is not felt that an increase in battery prices followed as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Battery Decree.<br />

484<br />

29/09/09


26.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The collection system may charge manufacturers who do not belong to the collection<br />

system for the costs <strong>of</strong> the sorting, recycling or disposal <strong>of</strong> the sorted batteries (Article<br />

4 Battery Decree).<br />

Infringements <strong>of</strong> the regulations, for the purposes <strong>of</strong> Article 61, Para 1, No. 5 <strong>of</strong> the<br />

German <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Recycling Act, are deemed to have been committed<br />

by parties who, for example, put batteries on the market contrary to the Battery<br />

Decrees provisions or do not take back batteries.<br />

26.12 Lessons Learned<br />

According to the Battery Directive 2006/66/EC, Member States must reach a<br />

collection quota <strong>of</strong> 45 % <strong>of</strong> portable batteries and accumulators put into circulation by<br />

2016. In Germany the increased awareness and participation <strong>of</strong> consumers in a free<br />

<strong>of</strong> charge collection system for used batteries has – after a period <strong>of</strong> about eight<br />

years – led to a total amount <strong>of</strong> 14,132 tonnes <strong>of</strong> portable batteries being collected<br />

in 2007, or around 42 % <strong>of</strong> the amount <strong>of</strong> portable batteries put on the market.<br />

The widespread and easy accessibility <strong>of</strong> collection boxes for end <strong>of</strong> life batteries is a<br />

prerequisite for the participation <strong>of</strong> consumers in the collection system and avoids<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> household batteries into the residual waste stream.<br />

However, the battery decree has no incentives for producers and consumers to shift<br />

the consumption in favour <strong>of</strong> secondary batteries.<br />

The discussion on the revision <strong>of</strong> the Battery Decree in Germany covers the following<br />

points:<br />

485<br />

� Producers and importers <strong>of</strong> Batteries shall register with one central body<br />

before they may put batteries into circulation;<br />

� Adoption <strong>of</strong> the collection rates <strong>of</strong> the new Battery Directive for used portable<br />

batteries and accumulators <strong>of</strong> 25% by 2012 and 45% by 2016;<br />

� Collection and recycling systems run by producers need an authorisation<br />

which should only be granted if concrete collection and recycling targets are<br />

met;<br />

� Extended labelling duty; and<br />

� Marketing prohibition for portable batteries with more than 0.0002% cadmium<br />

per weight.<br />

Key issues for the policy are:<br />

� Avoidance <strong>of</strong> free riders / all battery producers participate in take-back<br />

systems, like GRS (Gemeinsame Rücknahmesystem Batterien);<br />

� Collection and treatment infrastructure is tailored to the amount <strong>of</strong> GRS<br />

disposed;<br />

� Consumers need to find the take-back system convenient so they do not<br />

illegally dispose <strong>of</strong> batteries in the residual waste;<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


486<br />

� A key problem for the successful return <strong>of</strong> batteries is consumers hoarding<br />

70% <strong>of</strong> batteries at home for over 3 months; and<br />

� It is argued that a high quota <strong>of</strong> returned batteries can be only achieved<br />

through a collection close to the households. 570<br />

26.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

Essential elements required for this particular policy to be introduced are:<br />

� “Willingness” <strong>of</strong> the industry to come up with its producer responsibility, e.g.<br />

organizing the recycling system;<br />

� Cooperation between the retailers and manufacturers concerning the<br />

collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> batteries;<br />

� Capacity to build up a recycling infrastructure (e.g. sufficient collection points<br />

and personnel to service these etc);<br />

� No legal obstacle for a take-back system run by industry, e.g. anti-trust law;<br />

and<br />

� Existence <strong>of</strong> a central institution for organizing and monitoring the system, and<br />

to enforce in cases <strong>of</strong> non-compliance.<br />

570 Bundesverband der Deutschen Entsorgungswirtschaft e.V. (BDE), EUWID from 06.005.2003, p. 9.<br />

29/09/09


27.0 Plastic Bag Levy - Ireland<br />

27.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The plastic bag levy targets disposable plastic carrier bags with the specific intention<br />

<strong>of</strong> reducing their consumption. A tax <strong>of</strong> €0.15 per bag was introduced in Ireland on<br />

the 4th <strong>of</strong> March 2002 under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Environmental Levy) (Plastic<br />

Bag) Regulations 2001. On 1 st July 2007 the levy was increased from €0.15 to €0.22<br />

per bag. There are exemptions for smaller plastic bags that meet specific conditions<br />

and are used to store non-packaged goods such as dairy products, fruit and<br />

vegetables, nuts, confectionary, hot or cold cooked food and ice. These are known as<br />

levy-free bags. Re-usable plastic bags are also exempt as long as the charge for the<br />

bag exceeds €0.70.<br />

The levy is applied at the point <strong>of</strong> sale, and retailers are obliged to pass on the levy to<br />

the customer. The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government<br />

(DoEHLG) recently initiated a Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA) on the proposed<br />

legislation to increase levies on plastic shopping bags in August 2008. It is proposed<br />

that the existing rules governing the level <strong>of</strong> the levies (on landfill and plastic bags)<br />

(Sections 72 and 73 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act) are amended to allow the<br />

Minister sufficient flexibility to increase the levy without frequent recourse to primary<br />

legislation. The outcomes <strong>of</strong> the RIA are not yet published (as <strong>of</strong> October 31 st 2008).<br />

27.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The decision to introduce the plastic bag levy followed a 1999 study on behalf <strong>of</strong> the<br />

DoEHLG documenting the issues <strong>of</strong> plastic bags and their environmental impact. 571<br />

The report recommended a levy as the most appropriate means <strong>of</strong> reducing<br />

consumption <strong>of</strong> plastic shopping bags and thereby reducing consequent<br />

environmental problems.<br />

The levy was introduced primarily as an anti-litter measure, with plastic bags a highly<br />

visible component <strong>of</strong> litter, strongly associated in the public mind with the problem <strong>of</strong><br />

litter pollution. The materials used to make most plastic bags do not biodegrade<br />

(within any reasonable timeframe) and therefore persist in the environment unless<br />

collected. Plastic bags are <strong>of</strong>ten caught in trees, along river banks, in parks and other<br />

public spaces and can pose a danger to wildlife. This problem is <strong>of</strong>ten more acute in<br />

rural areas where local authorities do not have the capacity to provide regular<br />

street/road cleaning.<br />

The litter reduction objective is an important one to recognise. To the extent that<br />

plastic was deemed more problematic in this regard, switching to bags made <strong>of</strong> other<br />

571 Fehily, Timoney & Company (1999) Consultancy Study on Plastic Bags, Report prepared for the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment and Local Government, Dublin. Press Release March 2002.<br />

487<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


materials might not have been deemed to render the levy unsuccessful if those<br />

materials are less problematic in, or less likely to find their into, the litter stream.<br />

27.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The plastic bag levy was introduced on the 4 th March 2002.<br />

27.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The key organisations involved in implementation <strong>of</strong> the plastic bag levy are:<br />

488<br />

� <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government (DoEHLG);<br />

� Local Authorities who are in charge <strong>of</strong> enforcement;<br />

� The Controller and Auditor General; and<br />

� Retailers.<br />

A Service Level Agreement between the Revenue Commissioners and the DoEHLG<br />

provides that the Revenue Commissioners have responsibility in relation to collection<br />

<strong>of</strong> the levy and for ensuring that businesses are aware <strong>of</strong> their obligations in relation<br />

to making returns. This includes carrying out checks/audits on retailers, and other<br />

related activities.<br />

27.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

The key instruments for measurement <strong>of</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong> the levy include the sales data<br />

kept by the Revenue Commissioners, and industry data on sales <strong>of</strong> plastic bags.<br />

Table 27-1 details the Environment Fund Income generated from the plastic bags levy<br />

since its introduction in 2002. The income from the levy increased steadily from<br />

2002 to 2007. The introduction <strong>of</strong> the plastic bag levy in 2002 had an immediate<br />

effect on consumer behaviour – with plastic bag per capita usage decreasing from an<br />

estimated 328 bags to 21 plastic bags per capita per annum. However, the results <strong>of</strong><br />

the 2006 census indicated that plastic bag usage had risen to 31 bags per capita<br />

over the course <strong>of</strong> 2006. Consequently the levy was increased to 22 cents on 1 st July<br />

2007. 572<br />

Table 27-1: Plastic Bag Levy Income 2002 - 2007<br />

Plastic Plastic<br />

Plastic<br />

Bag Bag<br />

Bag<br />

Levy<br />

Levy<br />

29/09/09<br />

2002* 2002* 2003 2003 2004 2004 2005 2005 2006 2006 2006 2007<br />

2007<br />

€10,428,413 €12,883,408 €15,278,107 €17,484,551 €19,947,315 €22,577,535<br />

*Accounts for the period from the period from 17 th July 2001 to 31 st December 2002<br />

Source: Environment Fund Accounts from 2002 to 2007<br />

572 Press Release, 21/02/07 by the DoEHLG, “Plastic Bags Levy to be increased to 22c from the 1st <strong>of</strong><br />

July”.


27.5.1 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

489<br />

� Fehily Timoney & Company (1999) “Consultancy Study on Plastic Bags”, Report<br />

prepared for the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment and Local Government<br />

� S. McDonnell (2003) An Enquiry into the Use <strong>of</strong> Taxation on Environmentally<br />

Harmful Products: “A Case Study <strong>of</strong> the Irish Plastic Bag Levy” UCD Unpublished<br />

Thesis<br />

� The National Litter Pollution Monitoring System, <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment,<br />

Heritage and Local Government (2002 to present) (www.litter.ie)<br />

� Irish Business Against Litter (IBAL) and An Taisce (National Trust <strong>of</strong> Ireland)<br />

produced a number <strong>of</strong> litter surveys, January 2002 and April 2003;<br />

� Simon McDonnell and Susana Ferreira (2007) “The most popular tax in Europe?<br />

Lessons from the Irish plastic bags levy” Environmental and Resource<br />

Economics, September 2007, vol. 38, no. 1, pp. 1-11(11).<br />

27.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

The plastic bag levy has reduced consumption <strong>of</strong> plastic bags, which are highly visible<br />

components <strong>of</strong> litter and are very much associated in the public mind with the<br />

problem <strong>of</strong> litter pollution. It is not clear whether, and to what extent any<br />

environmental benefits have been <strong>of</strong>fset by switching to use <strong>of</strong> other bags.<br />

The effects <strong>of</strong> the tax on the use <strong>of</strong> plastic bags in retail outlets and in the landscape<br />

have been dramatic, with usage falling by more than 90%. 573 Since the introduction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the levy, the number <strong>of</strong> bags entering the consumption stream has been reduced<br />

by approximately 94% according to McDonnell. 574<br />

A combined project by Irish Business Against Litter (IBAL) and An Taisce (National<br />

Trust <strong>of</strong> Ireland) produced a number <strong>of</strong> litter surveys. These have found that between<br />

January 2002 and April 2003 the number <strong>of</strong> “clear” areas (i.e. areas in which there is<br />

no evidence <strong>of</strong> plastic bag litter) has increased by 21%, while the number <strong>of</strong> areas<br />

without “traces” has increased by 56%. 575<br />

The National Litter Pollution Monitoring System quantifies the composition <strong>of</strong> litter<br />

pollution in Ireland using litter quantification surveys (for further information please<br />

refer to www.litter.ie ). This Monitoring System allows the impact <strong>of</strong> the plastic bag<br />

levy to be evaluated; an illustration is given in Figure 27-1. Note that the DoEHLG<br />

573 Simon McDonnell and Susana Ferreira (2007) The most popular tax in Europe? Lessons from the<br />

Irish plastic bags levy, Environmental and Resource Economics, September 2007, vol. 38, no. 1, pp. 1-<br />

11(11).<br />

574 S. McDonnell (2003) An Enquiry into the Use <strong>of</strong> Taxation on Environmentally Harmful Products: A<br />

Case Study <strong>of</strong> the Irish Plastic Bag Levy, UCD, Unpublished Thesis.<br />

575 http://www.antaisce.org/projects/ibal.html.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


estimated the figure <strong>of</strong> 5% in their first Annual National Litter Pollution Monitoring<br />

Systems Annual Report, May 2003. 576 Consequently, one cannot be certain that the<br />

decline in litter quantities has been as dramatic as the figure would appear to<br />

suggest.<br />

Figure 27-1: Plastic Shopping Bags as a % <strong>of</strong> Litter<br />

490<br />

29/09/09<br />

5.00%<br />

4.50%<br />

4.00%<br />

3.50%<br />

3.00%<br />

2.50%<br />

2.00%<br />

1.50%<br />

1.00%<br />

0.50%<br />

Plastic Bags (Shopping Bags)<br />

5%<br />

0.32% 0.25% 0.22%0.22%<br />

0.52% 0.29% 0.32%<br />

0.00%<br />

Prior to Levy 2002 2003<br />

1<br />

2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

Source: National Litter Pollution Monitoring Systems, Annual Reports, www.litter.ie<br />

Prior to the introduction <strong>of</strong> the plastic bag levy in March 2002, it was estimated that<br />

1.3 billion shopping bags were issued annually, and that they contributed a visually<br />

very intrusive form <strong>of</strong> litter pollution. 577 The National Litter Pollution Monitoring<br />

Systems Survey results in Figure 4-1 show a significant decrease in the percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

plastic bags, from 5% prior to the Plastic Bag Levy to 0.32% in 2002. A further<br />

decrease to 0.22% followed in both the 2004 and 2005 survey periods. In 2006 the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> plastic bags, constituted 0.52% <strong>of</strong> the National Litter Composition.<br />

However in 2007 the percentage <strong>of</strong> plastic bags subsequently decreased to<br />

0.29%. 578 This decrease in 2007 may be attributable to the increase in the plastic<br />

bag levy to 22 cents on 1 st July 2007. In 2008, the percentage <strong>of</strong> plastic bags<br />

increased slightly to 0.32%.<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> the research for the paper on “The most popular tax in Europe? Lessons<br />

from the Irish plastic bags levy”, an evaluation <strong>of</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong> the levy on<br />

householders and retail sector was completed. This involved interviewing seven<br />

leaders in the retail sector and conducting random telephone interviews with<br />

consumers, the results being as follows:<br />

576 National Litter Pollution Monitoring Systems, Annual Report May 2003, www.litter.ie<br />

577 This further highlights, perhaps, the significance <strong>of</strong> ‘visibility’ as opposed to ‘counts’ in considering<br />

litter-related disamenity (as discussed in Section 16.6.3 <strong>of</strong> these Annexes).<br />

578 National Litter Pollution Monitoring Systems, Annual Reports, www.litter.ie


491<br />

� Retailers find the effects <strong>of</strong> the tax on their well-being neutral or positive, closely<br />

related to the fact that the additional costs <strong>of</strong> implementation were generally<br />

less than the savings resulting from not having to purchase plastic bags.<br />

Implementation costs were low because bookkeeping was integrated with VAT<br />

returns; and<br />

� Overall, consumers were very much in favour <strong>of</strong> the levy. The majority felt that<br />

the impact <strong>of</strong> the levy in terms <strong>of</strong> convenience at checkouts and more generally<br />

was enhanced, but that the levy had added to their expense. Virtually all<br />

respondents responded that they felt the impact on the environment was<br />

positive, producing a noticeable reduction in plastic bags ‘in the environment’.<br />

Fehily Timoney et al carried out an ex ante study on the impact <strong>of</strong> the tax on the<br />

plastic bag industry. 579 This study included a Life Cycle Assessment (LCA) <strong>of</strong> plastic<br />

and paper bags using a weighting system, based on how far away each impact was<br />

from a sustainable target level. Using this approach, plastic bags were shown to have<br />

a lower total impact score <strong>of</strong> 7.9 compared to paper bags with a score <strong>of</strong> 8.9. 580<br />

In this context, it is worth noting that it has been suggested that since the introduction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the plastic bag levy that paper shopping bags are more prevalent (though we can<br />

find no data on the consumption <strong>of</strong> paper bags before or after the ban, usage is<br />

expected to have increased). 581 Figure 27-2 below illustrates the percentage <strong>of</strong> paper<br />

bags as a percentage <strong>of</strong> the National Litter Composition from 2003 to 2008. The<br />

Litter Quantification Survey results available from the National Litter Pollution<br />

Monitoring System show that paper bags as a constituent element <strong>of</strong> litter pollution<br />

appear to be more or less stable, but crucially, as with plastic bags, no pre-levy data is<br />

available so one cannot assess whether the proportion <strong>of</strong> paper bags in litter has<br />

increased or not. Further study is needed to assess how bag consumption (both paper<br />

and plastic) has changed and what the resulting environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> the policy<br />

have been.<br />

In a study dated September 2004 completed by EuroCommerce which analysed<br />

plastic bags in an Integrated Product <strong>Policy</strong> (IPP) context the main conclusion stated<br />

that:<br />

“Little or negative gain was found to be derived from the shift from single use<br />

bags to other single use bags such as biodegradable bags and paper bags,<br />

with potential litter gains <strong>of</strong>fset by negative resource use, energy and<br />

greenhouse outcomes” 582 .<br />

579 Fehily, Timoney & Company (1999) Consultancy Study on Plastic Bags, Report prepared for the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment and Local Government, Dublin.<br />

580 Ibid.<br />

581 Sales figures for paper bags in the period before and after the Levy was requested from the<br />

DoEHLG, but this information does not exist.<br />

582 EuroCommerce, Environment & Logistics (September 2004) “The Use <strong>of</strong> LCAs on Plastic Bags in an<br />

IPP Context”.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Also, the report stated that there is a higher incidence <strong>of</strong> "double bagging" (people<br />

using two bags instead <strong>of</strong> one) for strength. The EuroCommerce report is based on<br />

Life Cycle Analysis (LCA), but no clear information is provided in the report. This report<br />

also suggests that paper bags have meant increased transport and storage costs, but<br />

no supporting information is <strong>of</strong>fered on this.<br />

Figure 27-2: Paper Bags as a Percentage <strong>of</strong> the National Litter Composition<br />

492<br />

29/09/09<br />

0.70%<br />

0.60%<br />

0.50%<br />

0.40%<br />

0.30%<br />

0.20%<br />

0.10%<br />

0.00%<br />

0.60% 0.57%<br />

Paper Bags<br />

0.40%<br />

0.61%<br />

0.42% 0.43%<br />

1<br />

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

Source: National Litter Pollution Monitoring Systems, Annual Reports, www.litter.ie<br />

27.6.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

In 2007, <strong>of</strong> the €57,725,535 generated in income from the Environmental Fund<br />

(€22,577,535 <strong>of</strong> which was generated in income from the plastic bag levy), the<br />

following was spent on Prevention Initiatives:<br />

� “<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and the National Market Development Group”, €1,518,213<br />

� “Producer Responsibility Initiatives”, €905,793<br />

� “Environmental Awareness”, €1,615,332<br />

The above figures illustrate that a large number <strong>of</strong> Environmental Awareness<br />

Campaigns and <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programmes have been put in place in local<br />

authorities, due to the monies available from the Environmental Fund. Therefore this<br />

levy has influenced preventative initiatives in Ireland.<br />

The Irish Plastic Bag Levy has caused an estimated 90% reduction in plastic bag<br />

production in Ireland. Prior to its introduction approx. 1.2 billion disposable plastic<br />

bags were given away free by retailers. There is no information on the quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

paper bags used in Ireland prior to the levy and following its implementation.<br />

As mentioned above, it has been suggested that since the introduction <strong>of</strong> the plastic<br />

bag levy, that paper shopping bags are more prevalent (though we can find no data<br />

on the consumption <strong>of</strong> paper bags before or after the ban, usage is expected to be<br />

increased). Surveys indicated, however, that up to 90% <strong>of</strong> shoppers used long-life


ags in 2003, compared with 36% in 1999, which suggests that the switch to paper<br />

bags was a far from universal switch. 583<br />

27.6.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

In 2007, <strong>of</strong> the €57,725,535 generated in income from the Environmental Fund<br />

(€22,577,535 <strong>of</strong> which was generated in income from the plastic bag levy), the<br />

following was spent on Recycling Initiatives:<br />

493<br />

� “<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> including Recycling Projects”, €17,246,428, this<br />

represents payments made to local authorities to assist in costs associated<br />

with the provision <strong>of</strong> waste management infrastructure.<br />

� “Recycling Operational Costs”, €11,914,847, this represents payments made<br />

to local authorities to assist in costs associated with the operational costs <strong>of</strong><br />

waste management.<br />

The above figures illustrate that a large number <strong>of</strong> recycling facilities/infrastructure<br />

have been put in place due to the monies available from the Environmental Fund.<br />

Therefore, although the direct effect <strong>of</strong> the levy on recycling appears to have been<br />

zero, indirectly, the plastic bag levy can be said to have had a positive impact on<br />

recycling in Ireland as it provides local authorities with the funding to develop<br />

recycling facilities. In addition, it would be easy to understate the potential influence<br />

on public awareness that such a policy may have had in making some citizens more<br />

aware <strong>of</strong> ‘waste’ as an issue <strong>of</strong> legitimate concern.<br />

27.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The set up (establishment) costs were €1.2 million. This included purchase <strong>of</strong> new<br />

computer systems and additional resources needed to administer the levy. Annual<br />

administration costs are in the order <strong>of</strong> €350,000. Advertising costs arising from the<br />

publicity campaign to launch the levy amounted to €358,000 584 .<br />

Receipts from the plastic bag levy amounted to €9.6 million in the first year. Taking<br />

into account start-up and ongoing administrative costs, total net receipts from the<br />

plastic bag levy amounted to around €8 million. The levy was expected to generate<br />

around €11 million in a full year; however the latest figure from the Environment Fund<br />

Accounts 2007 show the income from the levy was €22,577,535 in 2007, <strong>of</strong> this the<br />

Environmental Levy Collection Costs (the annual service fee agreed with the Revenue<br />

Commissioners for the operation <strong>of</strong> the plastic bag levy), amounted to €388,025 585 .<br />

This equates to approximately 17% <strong>of</strong> the revenue received.<br />

583 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage & Local Government, Press Release, 21/07/2007<br />

584 Simon McDonnell and Susana Ferreira (2007) The most popular tax in Europe? Lessons from the<br />

Irish plastic bags levy, Environmental and Resource Economics, September 2007, vol. 38, no. 1, pp. 1-<br />

11(11).<br />

585 Environment Funds Account (2007)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Enforcement costs borne by the Irish Government were minimal, as the tax receipts<br />

were provided to the Government along with revenues from the national Value Added<br />

Tax (VAT).<br />

27.8 Response from Public and Industry<br />

Much <strong>of</strong> the response from public and industry is described in Section 27.5. The<br />

plastic bag levy has had an immediate effect on consumer behaviour, creating a<br />

strong anti – litter awareness initiative and influencing behavioural change <strong>of</strong><br />

consumers by encouraging them to change their shopping practices and to buy reusable<br />

shopping bags. A national survey on the Environment "Attitudes and Actions<br />

2003" found that 91% <strong>of</strong> those surveyed believe the Plastic Bag Levy is a good idea.<br />

Among the many reasons given are that it is better for the environment, there are no<br />

plastic bags visible in the streets (it was also a rural problem with bags snagged in<br />

fences, hedgerows and trees) and that re-usable bags are more convenient for<br />

holding shopping. This is a major change in attitude as during the course <strong>of</strong> the<br />

previous survey in 1999, 40% <strong>of</strong> those surveyed stated they would not be willing to<br />

pay a levy. The 6% who did not believe that the levy was a good idea in the later<br />

survey cited the fact that they missed having plastic bags about the house and were<br />

also frustrated when they forgot to bring-usable bags into the shop. The survey also<br />

indicated that 90% <strong>of</strong> shoppers use reusable/long life bags, 6% use cardboard boxes,<br />

4 % plastic bags and 1% other means.<br />

After initial opposition to the tax, retailers ended up strongly supporting a bill, which<br />

saves €50million per year from reduced disposable grocery bag stocking costs whilst<br />

increasing sales <strong>of</strong> re-usable bags.<br />

The levy encourages people to think more about the products and services that they<br />

are using more broadly and raises an awareness <strong>of</strong> reuse and recycling in general.<br />

27.9 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Data from levies remitted and the results <strong>of</strong> the 2006 Census indicate that plastic<br />

bag usage rose to 31 bags per capita during the course <strong>of</strong> 2006 compared to 21<br />

bags per capita when the levy was introduced in 2002. (as highlighted above) To that<br />

effect the levy was increased to 22 cents on the 1 st July 2007. The aim <strong>of</strong> the<br />

increase is to reduce the per capita usage to the level achieved in 2002 or lower. This<br />

increase in the levy illustrates the desire to generate continuous incentives for<br />

improvement.<br />

It has also been seen that the manufacture <strong>of</strong> paper bags has increased since the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> the levy. One study reported that one paper bag manufacturer<br />

reported a 20 fold increase in sales, meaning they now produce ten million bags a<br />

year.<br />

The policy encourages people to think more about the products and services they are<br />

using and raise an awareness <strong>of</strong> reuse and recycling in general. There may have been<br />

effects on behaviour and technical change, which are not directly related to the levy<br />

itself.<br />

494<br />

29/09/09


27.10 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

In principle, the levy may be said to have a disproportionate economic impact on<br />

those on lower incomes. However, since the cost is low and readily avoidable this is<br />

not likely to be a significant issue, and the survey results would appear to bear this<br />

out.<br />

As regards bag producers, the producers <strong>of</strong> plastic bags will have been negatively<br />

affected, whilst those producing paper bags and ‘bags for life’ will have been<br />

beneficiaries. The structure <strong>of</strong> production <strong>of</strong> plastic bags suggests, however, that the<br />

prevalence <strong>of</strong> overseas production <strong>of</strong> bags may have implied that the negative impact<br />

on bag producers was felt mostly overseas. Fehily et al (1999) carried out an ex ante<br />

study on the impact <strong>of</strong> the tax on the plastic bag industry. 586 They estimated that in<br />

1999, 79% <strong>of</strong> the plastic bags consumed were imported (from the rest <strong>of</strong> the EU and<br />

certain Southeast Asian countries). Four plastic manufacturing firms operating in the<br />

Republic produced the remaining 21%. Since then, however, one has apparently gone<br />

out <strong>of</strong> business causing the loss <strong>of</strong> 26 jobs, but it is not clear whether this was as a s<br />

direct consequence <strong>of</strong> the levy.<br />

As the tax is imposed at the retail level on Irish shoppers, it does not introduce<br />

competitiveness concerns. The Republic <strong>of</strong> Ireland shares a land border with Northern<br />

Ireland, where there is no levy, but the costs to the consumers are such a minor<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> the total shopping bill, and the levy has proved, in any event, to be so<br />

popular with the public, that it is highly unlikely that there has been any leakage <strong>of</strong><br />

trade across the border caused by the levy. 587<br />

27.11 Complementary Policies<br />

Shopping bags are packaging waste under the 2004/12/EC (Packaging and<br />

Packaging <strong>Waste</strong> Directive). Hence, there is some complementarity with the policy on<br />

packaging more generally.<br />

27.12 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The policy effectively implies the elimination <strong>of</strong> a practice – the issuing <strong>of</strong> plastic bags<br />

free <strong>of</strong> charge – which will have led (as the policy’s effects suggest) to overconsumption<br />

<strong>of</strong> plastic bags. Whether the pricing is optimal is unclear, and the fact<br />

that other bags may be being issued free <strong>of</strong> charge might be said to imply some<br />

distortion <strong>of</strong> the market. Plastic bag manufacturers argue, for example, that plastic<br />

bag production is more energy efficient (in terms <strong>of</strong> use per quantum <strong>of</strong> ‘bag<br />

packaging’).<br />

586 Fehily, Timoney & Company (1999) Consultancy Study on Plastic Bags, Report prepared for the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment and Local Government, Dublin.<br />

587 Simon McDonnell and Susana Ferreira (2007) The most popular tax in Europe? Lessons from the<br />

Irish plastic bags levy, Environmental and Resource Economics, September 2007, vol. 38, no. 1, pp. 1-<br />

11(11).<br />

495<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The plastic bag levy has led to more expensive, long-life bags being developed in the<br />

market. These are considered to be more environmentally friendly as they are<br />

capable <strong>of</strong> being reused on an ongoing basis.<br />

27.13 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Some anecdotal evidence <strong>of</strong> slippage in the application <strong>of</strong> the plastic bag levy has<br />

been reported. Local authorities carry out inspections <strong>of</strong> retail outlets with a view to<br />

improving current practices in relation to the implementation <strong>of</strong> the plastic bag levy<br />

regulations. An enforcement network <strong>of</strong> local authority <strong>of</strong>ficers has been established<br />

to monitor and co-ordinate the enforcement drive for the plastic bag levy.<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> actions are undertaken by local authorities in ensuring compliance by<br />

retailers with the requirements <strong>of</strong> the levy regulations. These include visiting retail<br />

outlets and talking to retailers, carrying out initial spot checks and monitoring<br />

implementation.<br />

The role <strong>of</strong> the Revenue Commissioners relates to the collection <strong>of</strong> the levy. Revenue<br />

Commissioners are responsible for:<br />

496<br />

� Identification <strong>of</strong> accountable persons;<br />

� Processing returns and payments received from accountable persons;<br />

� Carrying out verification checks relating to the accuracy <strong>of</strong> returns;<br />

� Pursuing accountable persons who fail to deliver returns and payments within<br />

the statutory time limits;<br />

� Raising estimates where returns are not received or where liability is under<br />

stated;<br />

� Dealing with appeals against estimates raised.<br />

It is intended that, so as to minimise compliance costs on retailers, checks carried out<br />

by Revenue Commissioners will, ins<strong>of</strong>ar as possible, be incorporated with checks<br />

carried out in relation to tax liabilities.<br />

Retailers who fail to correctly implement the levy regulations are liable to the following<br />

sanctions:<br />

� 0n summary conviction, a fine not exceeding €3,000, or imprisonment for up<br />

to 12 months, or both; or<br />

� 0n conviction on indictment, a maximum fine <strong>of</strong> €15 million, or to<br />

imprisonment for up to 10 years, or both.<br />

� A system <strong>of</strong> daily fines applies where an <strong>of</strong>fence continues to be committed<br />

after conviction i.e. up to €1,000 per day for a summary conviction, or up to<br />

€130,000 for conviction on indictment.<br />

29/09/09


27.14 Lessons Learned<br />

27.14.1 General Lessons<br />

The plastic bag levy has been deemed a successful policy in Ireland, resulting in an<br />

estimated 90% reduction in plastic bag use in Ireland. Particular effects include:<br />

497<br />

� A decrease in the percentage <strong>of</strong> plastic bags as a littering item, from 5% prior<br />

to implementation <strong>of</strong> the levy to 0.29% in 2007, while the percentage <strong>of</strong> paper<br />

bags remained relatively constant at an average <strong>of</strong> 0.6% <strong>of</strong> all litter items<br />

nationally. It should be considered, however, that the pre-levy figure <strong>of</strong> 5% was<br />

an estimate;<br />

� More money in an environmental fund for environmental projects such as<br />

bring banks and new civic amenity sites which are contributing to the much<br />

improved recycling performance; and<br />

� The legislation encourages people to think more about the products and<br />

services they are using and raise an awareness <strong>of</strong> reuse and recycling in<br />

general.<br />

There are obvious advantages <strong>of</strong> this levy in terms <strong>of</strong> the significant decrease in the<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> plastic bags as a littering item. What seems less clear is whether the<br />

benefits unrelated to litter, in particular, whether those associated with use <strong>of</strong> bags,<br />

have been beneficial in net terms. In other words, has there been a waste prevention<br />

effect, and what has been the net environmental impact <strong>of</strong> the reduction in plastic<br />

bag usage, and the increased use <strong>of</strong> alternatives? All product levies can be expected<br />

to have ‘output’ and ‘substitution’ effects. In the absence <strong>of</strong> further analysis, net<br />

effects might be assumed to be positive, but one cannot be absolutely certain <strong>of</strong> this.<br />

It must be said that the Irish plastic bag levy has been something <strong>of</strong> an inspiration<br />

worldwide. Many jurisdictions are now seeking to implement similar levies or have<br />

already done so. The rationale for such levies is gaining increasing support from those<br />

concerned with marine pollution. 588<br />

588 See, for example, Ljubomir Jeftic, Seba Sheavly and Ellik Adler (2009) Marine Litter: A Global<br />

Challenge, Report for UNEP, April 2009,<br />

http://www.unep.org/regionalseas/marinelitter/publications/docs/Marine_Litter_A_Global_Challenge.<br />

pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


28.0 Packaging Taxes - <strong>International</strong><br />

28.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Packaging taxes are typically measures used to affect the production and<br />

management <strong>of</strong> packaging wastes. In most instances, packaging taxes are classified<br />

as an example <strong>of</strong> a ‘consumption’ tax whereby a levy is applied with the aim to<br />

discourage excess consumption and waste generation. Such levies can affect supply<br />

and demand <strong>of</strong> packaging through influencing the use <strong>of</strong> packaging materials,<br />

generally seeking to shift consumption towards packaging with lower environmental<br />

impacts.<br />

Levies are applied to materials used for packaging containers (normally in the retail<br />

sector). Varying rates are applied depending upon the materials used. These<br />

materials include (amongst others) different types <strong>of</strong> plastic, cardboard, aluminium,<br />

glass and wood. The levy is normally applied as a weight based incentive, but can also<br />

based on volume when concerned with liquid packaging, especially where the<br />

intention is to encourage re-use. 589<br />

28.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

Within the EU, Denmark, Belgium and the Netherlands have each applied a form <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging tax. Product taxes in Belgium are discussed in further detail in Section<br />

30.0.<br />

Denmark has had a packaging tax in operation since 1978, with significant changes<br />

made over the last decade. 590 Between 1999 and 2001, Denmark introduced a more<br />

sophisticated version <strong>of</strong> the tax which removed fiscal equality between different<br />

packaging materials. The revised taxes are now determined through reference to life<br />

cycle-based assessment <strong>of</strong> the environmental damages associated with the different<br />

materials.<br />

The most recent country to adopt a packaging tax is the Netherlands, adopting their<br />

packaging tax in January 2008. The tax in the Netherlands is known as the Carbon-<br />

Based Packaging Tax. The tax considers the life cycle impact <strong>of</strong> materials based on<br />

greenhouse gas emissions and is applied using a relevant metric to each material.<br />

It appears that in both the Netherlands and in Denmark, the tax has been<br />

implemented for a variety <strong>of</strong> objectives including:<br />

498<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> prevention;<br />

589 National Environmental Research Institute, Denmark (2006) The Use <strong>of</strong> Economic Instruments in<br />

Nordic and Baltic Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> 2001-2005, Final report for Nordic Council <strong>of</strong> Ministers, 2006.<br />

590 ECOTEC in association with CESAM, C. U. (2001) Study on Environmental Taxes and Charges in the<br />

European Union and its Member States, Final report for the European Commission, April 2001.<br />

29/09/09


499<br />

� Higher rates <strong>of</strong> recycling; and<br />

� Reduced environmental / climate change impacts.<br />

28.2.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

Packaging taxes have been implemented in different ways in different countries.<br />

These variations include the materials to which the tax applies, the minimum<br />

threshold applied, exempt items and the rate <strong>of</strong> tax itself. Table 28-1 demonstrates<br />

the variations between tax rates on packaging material in Denmark and the<br />

Netherlands.<br />

Table 28-1: Primary Packaging Tax Rates 2008 (weight-based)<br />

Packaging Packaging Packaging<br />

Denmark Denmark ( (€/kg) ( €/kg)<br />

Virgin Cardboard and Paper 0.13<br />

Recycled Cardboard and Paper 0.07<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

€/kg) 591 Ne<br />

Ne Netherlands Ne therlands ( (€/kg) (<br />

€/kg)<br />

0.06<br />

Virgin Plastics (except<br />

polystyrene and PVC) 1.74 0.36<br />

Recycled Plastics (except<br />

polystyrene and PVC) 1.04<br />

Filled Plastics (except<br />

polystyrene and PVC) 1.04<br />

Plastics (except polystyrene and<br />

PVC) UN-approved 1.39<br />

Polystyrene and PVC 2.73<br />

Aluminium 4.47 0.57<br />

Tinplate and Steel 1.24<br />

Tinplate and Steel, UN-approved 0.99<br />

Glass and Ceramics 0.25 0.05<br />

Wood 0.07 0.02<br />

Other Metals No comparable levy 0.11<br />

Bioplastics No comparable levy 0.18<br />

Other Materials No comparable levy 0.10<br />

€/kg) 592<br />

The scope <strong>of</strong> the schemes can also vary widely. In the Netherlands the scheme is<br />

believed to cover 95% <strong>of</strong> all packaging materials, whilst in Denmark only 20% <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging is covered within the scheme. 593 The Danish system covers products such<br />

591 The Danish Ministry <strong>of</strong> Taxation (2008) Packaging Tax Rates, consulted October 2008<br />

http://www.skm.dk/foreign/english/2087.html<br />

592 The Dutch Tax and Customs Administration (2008) Packaging Tax Rates, consulted October 2008<br />

http://www.belastingdienst.nl/zakelijk/verpakkingenbelasting/<br />

593 Ernst and Young Indirect Tax Alert, January 2008.


as drinks, oils, vinegar, sauces, dairy products, detergents, paints, cosmetics and pet<br />

food. 594 Currently the levy does not cover other items such as general foodstuffs and<br />

household goods and only applies to retail containers up to 20 litre capacity. 595<br />

The rates for beverage packaging in Denmark implied by the above levies are shown<br />

in Figure 28-1.<br />

Figure 28-1: Tax on Beverage Packaging in Denmark<br />

Source: Christian Fischer (2008) Producer Responsibility Schemes Versus Deposits<br />

and Taxes- Danish Experiences, PRO Europe Congress, 15 May 2008<br />

28.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

In both Denmark and the Netherlands, the Ministry for Taxation is responsible for<br />

setting the levy and recovering the funds from the scheme. An Environmental<br />

Protection Agency is normally responsible for the monitoring <strong>of</strong> the data relating to<br />

the scheme, whilst the initial legislation forming the scheme normally originates from<br />

the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment.<br />

Key organisations in the Danish implementation are shown in Table 28-2.<br />

594 The Danish Ministry <strong>of</strong> Taxation (2008) Packaging Tax Rates, consulted October 2008<br />

http://www.skm.dk/foreign/english/2087.html<br />

595 Ibid.<br />

500<br />

29/09/09


Table 28-2: The Organisation <strong>of</strong> the Danish Packaging Tax<br />

Transposition <strong>of</strong> directive into national<br />

legislation<br />

501<br />

Activity Activity<br />

Responsible Responsible body<br />

body<br />

Monitoring <strong>of</strong> meeting targets (national +<br />

directive)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment (Danish EPA)<br />

Danish EPA<br />

Monitoring and control <strong>of</strong> compliance Danish EPA/Local authorities<br />

Information on management <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

waste<br />

Local authorities and Dansk Retursystem<br />

Supplier <strong>of</strong> packaging data Danish EPA<br />

Collection Collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> packaging packaging waste:<br />

waste:<br />

— from households<br />

Local authorities and Dansk Retursystem<br />

(disposable beverage packaging)<br />

— from industry/commerce Mainly private operators<br />

Recycling and treatment <strong>of</strong> packaging waste<br />

Expenditure on packaging system covered by<br />

Source: EEA Report No 3/2005<br />

Private operators (recycling) and local<br />

authorities (treatment)<br />

Local authorities (via fees paid by<br />

households) and private enterprises<br />

28.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

In Denmark, the modern version <strong>of</strong> the packaging tax (post 2001) was conceived<br />

from the Danish Action Plan for <strong>Waste</strong> (1993-1997). This action plan called for an<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> the possibilities for taxing packaging as a means <strong>of</strong> influencing<br />

consumer behaviour. 596 Alongside this, there was also a desire to examine the<br />

environmental impact <strong>of</strong> different types <strong>of</strong> packaging and relate the levy to those<br />

findings.<br />

Before implementation <strong>of</strong> the modern version <strong>of</strong> the levy in Denmark, initial studies<br />

were conducted in 1993/94 to assess the feasibility <strong>of</strong> the packaging tax. 597 These<br />

initial studies concluded that the levy was not to be taken forward due to poor data<br />

and a lack <strong>of</strong> methodology for developing a comprehensive, environmentally<br />

beneficial, taxation system. In addition, it was perceived that the administrative<br />

burden <strong>of</strong> the tax was too high.<br />

596 ECOTEC in association with CESAM, C. U. (2001) Study on Environmental Taxes and Charges in the<br />

European Union and its Member States, Final report for the European Commission, April 2001<br />

597 Ibid.


In 1996, the Danish Parliament required the Government to again examine<br />

possibilities for the introduction <strong>of</strong> a tax. 598 The Government completed a review at<br />

the end <strong>of</strong> 1997, which recommended that:<br />

502<br />

� The tax should seek to reduce the weight <strong>of</strong> packaging for each particular<br />

material;<br />

� The tax should be based on a life cycle assessment <strong>of</strong> environmental impacts<br />

in order to promote the most environmentally friendly materials;<br />

� The tax should be based on weight <strong>of</strong> packaging and be differentiated by<br />

material; and<br />

� For ease <strong>of</strong> administration, only the heaviest product groups should be<br />

included, and it should be easy to distinguish the products and packaging on<br />

which the tax is imposed;<br />

Following the review, these findings were utilised in the framework for the levy in<br />

Denmark.<br />

In the Netherlands, two studies were used to assess the potential tax rates:<br />

• First, in 2007, approximate calculations were carried out by CE Delft for the<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> Finance on environmental differentiation <strong>of</strong> the packaging on a limited<br />

number <strong>of</strong> product groups. Some <strong>of</strong> the environmental data used in that study for<br />

the materials in question were outdated;<br />

• Second, again in 2007, with the decision having been taken to use the tax to<br />

cover all packaging, a second study was prepared though with only limited<br />

differentiation as to material subcategories (to keep things compatible with<br />

the existing Dutch monitoring system for packaging materials) It was known<br />

that the plan was to levy the packaging tax as a surcharge per kilo <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging material. 599<br />

28.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The use <strong>of</strong> life cycle assessment has been used by both Denmark and the<br />

Netherlands to seek to link the packaging taxes to a measure <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

impacts. In principle, basing a tax on these grounds ought – if the analysis is robust<br />

over time – to make evaluation <strong>of</strong> impacts simple. In principle, one would like to see<br />

revenues decline, or at least to see the trend in any revenue increase which would<br />

have occurred had the tax been applied earlier, reduced.<br />

From 1997 to 2001 packaging waste generation in Denmark only grew 2%, as<br />

opposed to the 8.4% rate for the EU-15, and against a backdrop <strong>of</strong> GDP growth in the<br />

598 Ibid.<br />

599 CE Delft (2007) Environmental Indices for the Dutch Packaging Tax, Delft: CE Delft, November<br />

2007.<br />

29/09/09


same period <strong>of</strong> 9.8%. 600 The Danish EPA hopes that by taxing materials that are<br />

deemed more environmentally damaging, packaging manufacturers will shift away<br />

from these materials to the less damaging materials. As even those materials that<br />

are less environmentally damaging still carry taxation it is hoped that total packaging<br />

use will be minimised by the tax. There has been no study conducted on the shifts in<br />

behavioural patterns caused by the tax but it may be hypothesised that the above<br />

mentioned changes could be expected at the margin. An increase in the price <strong>of</strong><br />

heavily packaged materials and media coverage <strong>of</strong> the taxation, may help to induce<br />

the producer to use, and the consumer to purchase, lightly packaged products.<br />

Due to the nature <strong>of</strong> the levy and its connection with consumption, the primary<br />

environmental outcome <strong>of</strong> the levy is anticipated to be waste prevention. According to<br />

the Nordic Council, the tax on packaging in Denmark has led to an annual 400,000<br />

tonnes reduction in packaging. 601 Figure 28-2 suggests that the total number <strong>of</strong> units<br />

consumed for beers and carbonated s<strong>of</strong>t drinks have declined over time. There has<br />

been a switch away from refillable to one-way packaging over this period.<br />

Figure 28-2: Beers and Carbonated S<strong>of</strong>t Drinks in Denmark Related to Refillable and<br />

One-way Packaging<br />

Source: Christian Fischer (2008) Producer Responsibility Schemes Versus Deposits<br />

and Taxes- Danish Experiences, PRO Europe Congress, 15 May 2008<br />

600 European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> packaging<br />

waste management systems in selected countries: an EEA pilot study, European Topic Centre on<br />

Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, Copenhagen.<br />

601 The Nordic Council (2008) Extension <strong>of</strong> environmental taxes, consulted October 2008<br />

http://www.norden.org/webb/news/news.asp?id=6237<br />

503<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Because the packaging tax is new in the Netherlands, no post-implementation studies<br />

are available to date. It is interesting to note, however, the relative rates applied in<br />

the Danish, Dutch and Belgian systems (see Table 28-3). These highlight the fact that<br />

in all systems, aluminium is deemed to be the material which should attract the<br />

highest tax rate. One problem with both approaches is that they do not appear to take<br />

into account whether the material is primary or secondary in origin.<br />

Table 28-3: Relative Environmental Scores <strong>of</strong> Packaging Materials in Belgium,<br />

Denmark and the Netherlands (per kilogram and with glass set to 1)<br />

504<br />

29/09/09<br />

Material Material Material<br />

Belgium Belgium Belgium<br />

Denmark Denmark Denmark Netherlands<br />

Netherlands<br />

Netherlands<br />

Paper & board 0<br />

0.3 recycling<br />

0.5 no recycling<br />

Glass 1 1 1<br />

Steel 5 5 2.5<br />

Aluminium 18 18 12.6<br />

Plastics 7 PS & PVC<br />

4-7<br />

11 EPS & PVC<br />

Source: CE Delft (2007) Environmental Indices for the Dutch Packaging Tax, Delft: CE<br />

Delft, November 2007.<br />

28.6 Implementation Costs<br />

When considering the scheme in Denmark, the Tax and Customs Administration<br />

Ministry invested 1.9 MDKK (~€0.25m) in information and technology systems in<br />

order to collect and administer the tax. 602 The operating cost for 1999 was 0.2 MDKK<br />

(~€300k), with an additional 5 full-time equivalents per annum required to operate<br />

the scheme. 603<br />

In many instances, the packaging tax is perceived to be more difficult to collect than<br />

other taxes due to there being a number <strong>of</strong> definitions to be checked and<br />

assessments to be made in relation to the products covered by the list <strong>of</strong> customs<br />

codes. Furthermore, the tax is collected from quite a large number <strong>of</strong> producers<br />

rather than being specific to just a few companies.<br />

In the Netherlands, although 95% <strong>of</strong> packaging products / materials are covered by<br />

levies, the first 15,000kg <strong>of</strong> packaging for each business is exempt from tax. This<br />

means that 98% <strong>of</strong> businesses will incur no liability for packaging tax. It is believed<br />

602 ECOTEC in association with CESAM, C. U. (2001) Study on Environmental Taxes and Charges in the<br />

European Union and its Member States, Final report for the European Commission, April 2001.<br />

603 Ibid.<br />

1.5<br />

7.8


that only 8,000-10,000 businesses will be liable for the tax. 604 Businesses that<br />

supply packaged products on the Dutch market are also liable to the tax. This<br />

includes manufacturers, importers, wholesalers and retailers.<br />

28.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Material based taxes such as this may be anticipated to drive technical change for<br />

the production industry to use alternative packaging materials (where the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

more environmentally damaging materials become more expensive than alternatives).<br />

Of course packaging minimisation (with material use efficiency balanced against<br />

product protection) is also stimulated by increased costs <strong>of</strong> using materials which<br />

constitute packaging.<br />

28.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The Danish EPA is not aware <strong>of</strong> any studies carried out on the distributional effects <strong>of</strong><br />

the tax. In principle, the tax is rather small and is unlikely to affect product prices<br />

significantly. Hence, although it has the potential to be regressive, its impacts are<br />

unlikely to be significant in and <strong>of</strong> themselves.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> management industries involved with final treatment are expected to see<br />

some decline in activity whereas those involved with recycling, re-use and<br />

minimisation should see their sector grow.<br />

The policy could have a strong impact on industries such as steel and aluminium, i.e.<br />

they are subject to the highest taxation rates, since they are deemed more<br />

environmentally damaging. Conversely, those taxed at lower rates could benefit from<br />

material switching. The unit rates, however, are not necessarily representative <strong>of</strong> the<br />

strength <strong>of</strong> incentive to switch from one material to another since the functional units<br />

<strong>of</strong> packaging require different weights <strong>of</strong> the different materials.<br />

28.9 Complementary Policies<br />

In Denmark, the packaging tax is designed to compliment other existing marketbased<br />

instruments. In particular, the scheme compliments the deposit refund scheme<br />

for drinks containers. Within the Danish system, drinks containers are subject to a<br />

levy based upon their volume rather than their weight. This variation in the tax<br />

encourages containers to be reused many times, because payment <strong>of</strong> the tax is only<br />

required on new containers entering the market – reuse is thus encouraged over<br />

recycling by this scheme.<br />

In the Netherlands, the tax effectively complements the voluntary agreement between<br />

central and local government in respect <strong>of</strong> packaging collection.<br />

604 Ernst and Young Indirect Tax Alert, January 2008.<br />

505<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


28.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

Where the packaging tax has been implemented in co-ordination with a life cycle<br />

analysis, resources are valued in relation to the damage they impact upon the<br />

environment. In principle, this should be a positive development and is aligned with<br />

standard economic theory in terms <strong>of</strong> improving the efficiency <strong>of</strong> the functioning <strong>of</strong><br />

markets. Arguably, the Danish approach is more ‘correct’, since it does not confine<br />

itself to climate change-based externalities only.<br />

Even so, this pricing has drawn criticism by some groups (e.g. Beverage Can Makers<br />

Europe) as the life cycle analysis is seen as having the ability to ‘distort’ decisionmaking.<br />

Industry does, however, have a habit <strong>of</strong> criticising instruments which seek to<br />

bring about change in materials use on the basis <strong>of</strong> their being ‘distorting’ even where<br />

they set out earnestly to reflect – however imperfectly – the externalities associated<br />

with material use. The system has also been criticised in Denmark, where there is no<br />

distinction between recycled aluminium and virgin product. 605 This would seem to<br />

ignore the benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling aluminium in this tax system.<br />

In the Netherlands, the relative tax rates seek to account for the way in which a given<br />

material is managed in the country’s waste management system. This itself presents<br />

problems since, in principle, as the management routes change, so the relative tax<br />

rates ought to change too. If, on the other hand, the measure is not intended to<br />

change these management routes, then arguably, it loses its potency as an<br />

instrument, although it still raises revenue.<br />

This brief discussion highlights two points:<br />

506<br />

29/09/09<br />

a) the intention <strong>of</strong> packaging taxes is to “distort” decision making, if by this,<br />

one understands the intention to change decisions on packaging<br />

b) a critical issue is the boundaries for the analysis and how the tax rates are<br />

met. Clearly, applying uniform rates for virgin and recycled materials does<br />

not reflect the environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> the packaging<br />

28.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

In Denmark the packaging tax has created some issues for importers <strong>of</strong> packaged<br />

products in that they need to know the packaging material and packaging weight <strong>of</strong><br />

all the goods which they import. Some importers have found it difficult to obtain<br />

accurate information from their suppliers and have struggled to comply with the<br />

regulations. The de minimis level applied in the Dutch tax should make enforcement<br />

relatively more straightforward since this reduces the number who are targeted by the<br />

policy.<br />

605 ECOTEC in association with CESAM, C. U. (2001) Study on Environmental Taxes and Charges in the<br />

European Union and its Member States, Final report for the European Commission, April 2001.


28.12 Lessons Learned<br />

The Danish scheme is considered by many to be successful. Success factors for the<br />

system are:<br />

507<br />

� Good coverage <strong>of</strong> materials covered by the tax;<br />

� A switch from weight based taxation to LCA tax; and<br />

� Tax levels set high enough to have an impact.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


29.0 Tyre Charge - <strong>International</strong><br />

29.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

A charge on the purchase <strong>of</strong> new tyres is an example <strong>of</strong> a technique used to<br />

encourage the use <strong>of</strong> retreaded tyres, and in some cases, also fund the recycling and<br />

safe disposal <strong>of</strong> waste tyres.<br />

Although waste tyres are relatively inert and decompose over a long period <strong>of</strong> time,<br />

they can pose a risk to the environment. Predominantly, the most <strong>of</strong>t-cited problem<br />

with waste tyres are uncontrolled fires – these can occur if large numbers <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

tyres are stockpiled. Whilst tyres are difficult to ignite, once alight, tyre fires can be<br />

extremely difficult to control and can cause both air and water pollution. 606 There are<br />

also problems with the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste tyres. Landfilling tyres is problematic as<br />

tyres are large and bulky, therefore occupying a large amount <strong>of</strong> space. Within the EU,<br />

the landfill directive has effectively banned the landfilling <strong>of</strong> tyres.<br />

Schemes aimed at combating and treating waste tyres can vary in both scope (types<br />

<strong>of</strong> tyres) and size (spatial coverage). Many, however, do have the common<br />

characteristic <strong>of</strong> targeting the larger part <strong>of</strong> the waste stream - car tyres. A common<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> nearly all <strong>of</strong> the schemes appears to be to a desire to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

tyres in the waste stream and to help fund and enable recycling/re-use/recovery <strong>of</strong><br />

waste tyres that do arise.<br />

In general, there are two main types <strong>of</strong> product levies used for waste tyres. The first<br />

type <strong>of</strong> product levy is the most simple and is not widely utilised. This type is<br />

effectively a simple product tax. Applied to waste tyres, the tax incentivises the use <strong>of</strong><br />

lower cost alternatives – notably, retreaded tyres - over new tyres. By discouraging the<br />

consumer from buying new tyres, the authority is able to ‘promote’ the reuse <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

tyres. The promotion <strong>of</strong> retreated tyres and alternatives to landfill are important aims<br />

<strong>of</strong> the tax. Importantly, the tax revenue accrued is not normally ‘ring-fenced’ and<br />

therefore, not used solely for the maintenance <strong>of</strong> the scheme (strictly speaking, if the<br />

revenue is used in the scheme it is a hypothecated tax, or if the revenue is used top<br />

provide a service proportionate to the payment, it would be a charge).<br />

Drawing comparisons to other product taxes, this simple scheme is very similar to the<br />

way taxes are used on plastic bags in some countries. There is, however, an exception<br />

whereby the price elasticity <strong>of</strong> new tyres is perhaps smaller than for plastic bags as<br />

consumers seem less willing to resort to alternatives, even where these are available<br />

and where the cost is comparable.<br />

The second type <strong>of</strong> charge differs in that revenue accrued from the charge is<br />

managed differently. In these schemes, revenues accrued from the product charge<br />

are only directed towards the recycling or reuse <strong>of</strong> waste tyres. Normally operated by<br />

606 http://www.ciwm.co.uk/pma/1579 consulted January 2009.<br />

508<br />

29/09/09


a government body, the revenue is ‘ring-fenced’ and only spent on the scheme. It is,<br />

however, unlikely that there would only be government involvement in to the scheme.<br />

In some cases, industry has requested more involvement in the management <strong>of</strong> the<br />

schemes. Consequently some schemes have evolved into ‘enhanced producer<br />

responsibility schemes’ or ‘extended producer responsibility schemes’. These<br />

schemes differ in their operation in that, as inferred by their name, a group <strong>of</strong><br />

producers take responsibility for the scheme. Collection <strong>of</strong> the revenue is operated<br />

through a not-for-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation owned and operated by industry. Typically in<br />

these schemes, the charge levied on the consumer becomes an ‘advanced disposal<br />

fee’.<br />

29.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

Implementing a product levy for new tyres has been common practice throughout<br />

Europe and North America over the last couple <strong>of</strong> decades. Most uses <strong>of</strong> charging<br />

have occurred where car use is highest, and thus, waste tyre arisings are also high.<br />

In both Europe and North America, revenue raised by levies has been used to prevent<br />

the mass storage and/or landfilling <strong>of</strong> tyres. In some instances, schemes have been<br />

benchmarked against a target, most <strong>of</strong>ten a recycling target, in order to assess<br />

performance. In Denmark, for example, at least 80% <strong>of</strong> waste tyres are required to be<br />

captured for recycling.<br />

In Europe, a range <strong>of</strong> policy options have been used to tackle problems with waste<br />

tyres. The most notable Member States using a product levy are Denmark 607 and<br />

Hungary. 608 In some other member states, producer responsibility schemes are used<br />

without the addition <strong>of</strong> a product levy per se, but where the scheme probably implies<br />

an increase in the price <strong>of</strong> tyres as a consequence <strong>of</strong> fees paid to schemes.<br />

In North America, the use <strong>of</strong> product levies is common place across states and<br />

provinces on the continent. Some notable localities that have introduced product<br />

levies include Texas and Rhode Island in the USA, and the provinces <strong>of</strong> British<br />

Columbia and Ontario in Canada. In the case <strong>of</strong> Rhode Island, the product levy is used<br />

in conjunction with a deposit-refund scheme.<br />

In both Texas (1997) and Ontario (1993) the product levy schemes have ceased<br />

operation. In Ontario, however, a new replacement scheme is due to be launched as<br />

there is still a significant problem with the storage and disposal <strong>of</strong> waste tyres. The<br />

preceding product levy scheme was originally managed by the government and<br />

received much adverse attention as the revenue generated was not re-allocated in to<br />

607<br />

http://www2.mst.dk/common/Udgivramme/Frame.asp?http://www2.mst.dk/Udgiv/publications/200<br />

1/87-7944-519-5/html/kap11_eng.htm<br />

608<br />

http://www.magyarorszag.hu/english/keyevents/a_vallalk/a_adopenz/a_vallalkadok/a_kvtermekdij2<br />

0080425.html#paragr1<br />

509<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


tackling problems with tyres. The proposed new scheme is intended to be an<br />

enhanced producer responsibility scheme.<br />

29.2.1 Country-Specific Characteristics<br />

Variations in the type, use and magnitude <strong>of</strong> the levy occur throughout the differing<br />

countries, states and provinces that have implemented a charge. Table 29-1 shows<br />

the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the charge in a selected number <strong>of</strong> examples. Please note that<br />

unlike other governments, Hungary has opted to use a weight based charge instead<br />

<strong>of</strong> a charge on each individual tyre.<br />

Table 29-1: Characteristics <strong>of</strong> Different Charging Regimes for Car Tyres<br />

Country/Sta<br />

Country/State/Province<br />

Country/Sta te/Province Operating Operating period period Nature Nature <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> charge charge Charge Charge Charge per per tyre tyre tyre ( (€) ( €)<br />

Denmark 1995 - current 8 DKK per tyre 1.07<br />

Hungary unknown 110 HUF/kg * 2.56<br />

Rhode Island, USA 1993 – current $0.50 per tyre 0.38<br />

British Columbia, Canada 1991 - current C$3.00 per tyre 1.85<br />

Texas, USA 1992 - 1997 $2.00 per tyre 1.52<br />

Ontario, Canada 1989 - 1993 C$5.00 per tyre 3.11<br />

*Note: Average tyre weight is 6.5kg according to<br />

www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/UK_Used_Tyre_Market_Report_2004_Report.dd09e6dd.2904.pdf<br />

Variations also exist in the types <strong>of</strong> tyres involved in the schemes. Whilst most<br />

schemes seem to exclude smaller bicycle tyres, some schemes choose to include<br />

larger agricultural and industrial tyres. This report, however, focuses upon passenger<br />

car tyres, reflecting the main target <strong>of</strong> these levies.<br />

29.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The organisation responsible for the management <strong>of</strong> the levy can vary dependent on<br />

the type <strong>of</strong> scheme implemented, and in particular, the intended destination and use<br />

<strong>of</strong> the levy. In the cases <strong>of</strong> product taxes, the management <strong>of</strong> the scheme is normally<br />

undertaken by a government agency or government body.<br />

Where an enhanced producer responsibility scheme is utilised, revenue accrued is<br />

usually managed by a not-for-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation, normally operated by industry. The<br />

organisation is also responsible for facilitating recycling activities by utilising the<br />

revenue accrued through the fund. In these cases, however, depending upon the way<br />

in which the initiative emerges, government agencies are typically involved in<br />

enforcement and in target setting.<br />

Selected examples <strong>of</strong> different schemes follow.<br />

29.3.1 Rhode Island - Hard-to-Dispose Materials<br />

In 1993 the ‘Hard to Dispose Material’ tax was introduced by the Rhode Island<br />

Division <strong>of</strong> Taxation. The tax covers all new tyres, but also includes varying rates <strong>of</strong><br />

taxation for other, difficult to dispose materials. These include:<br />

510<br />

29/09/09


511<br />

� Lubricating oil;<br />

� Antifreeze; and<br />

� Organic solvents<br />

The Rhode Island Division <strong>of</strong> Taxation is also responsible for the administration <strong>of</strong> the<br />

revenues accrued. Unlike most other schemes in the USA, there is no involvement<br />

from the State Environmental Agency (Rhode Island <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environmental<br />

<strong>Management</strong>) in the management <strong>of</strong> the fund. The scheme is also used in<br />

conjunction with a deposit-refund scheme to ensure the maximum capture <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

tyres.<br />

29.3.2 British Columbia - FIRST<br />

The Financial Incentives for Recycling Scrap Tires (FIRST) Programme was first set up<br />

as a simple product levy scheme but has now evolved into an enhanced producer<br />

responsibility scheme. Initiated in 1991, the programme was managed by the<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment. The Ministry were also responsible for the funding <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling initiatives from the revenue accrued from the programme. The provincial<br />

government was responsible for the overall compliance and enforcement <strong>of</strong> the<br />

programme.<br />

In 2007, the programme changed hands, and has now become an enhanced<br />

producer responsibility scheme. It was believed that the revenue accrued from the tax<br />

was not successfully directed to meet the programme’s aims, which were combating<br />

the large scale storage <strong>of</strong> waste tyres and assisting with the recycling <strong>of</strong> waste tyres.<br />

The programme is now operated by ‘Tire Stewardship British Columbia’ - a not-forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

organisation operated by the tyre industry. Key changes to the programme<br />

include a change in the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the charge - from $3 to $4 per tyre for most<br />

customers - and the utilisation <strong>of</strong> all <strong>of</strong> the revenue raised by the scheme as directed<br />

by the organisation itself.<br />

29.3.3 Texas – <strong>Waste</strong> Tire Recycling Fund<br />

Although no longer functioning, Texas operated a product charge on new tyres from<br />

1992-1997. The charge was used in conjunction with a ban on landfilling waste tyres.<br />

The formation <strong>of</strong> the programme, the ‘<strong>Waste</strong> Tire Recycling Fund’, was the<br />

responsibility <strong>of</strong> the State Legislature. The State Legislature was also responsible for<br />

overseeing the scheme and ultimately made the decision to close the programme.<br />

Whilst operational, the day-to-day management <strong>of</strong> the fund was undertaken by the<br />

Texas Commission on Environmental Quality (TCEQ) – the State Environmental<br />

Agency. TCEQ also ensured that retailers <strong>of</strong> tyres paid in to the fund.<br />

The fund closed in 1997 as the programme was deemed unsuccessful. Although<br />

closing over 700 illegal tyre storage sites and helping develop the recycling industry,<br />

the scheme left behind a large stockpile <strong>of</strong> shredded tyres as an emerging recycling<br />

industry was unable to process all <strong>of</strong> the tyres.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


29.3.4 Denmark<br />

In 1995, the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment and Energy entered an agreement with the<br />

Danish Motor Trade Association and the Association <strong>of</strong> Danish Recycling Industries to<br />

implement a charge on the purchase <strong>of</strong> new tyres. The agreement also included a<br />

minimum recycling target <strong>of</strong> 80% by 2004. The charge is used to help implement the<br />

ban on the landfill <strong>of</strong> tyres (through the Landfill Directive).<br />

The enhanced producer responsibility scheme is operated by the Danish Tyre Trade<br />

Environmental Foundation, which uses the revenue accrued by the scheme to fund<br />

the transport and recycling <strong>of</strong> waste tyres.<br />

29.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

Our research has yet to discover any pre or post implementation studies.<br />

29.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

Dependant on the locality, and therefore the scheme aims, the main environmental<br />

benefits delivered through this policy can vary. Many programmes have the common<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> promoting the recycled tyres industry and reducing the overall total number <strong>of</strong><br />

tyres stockpiled. Stockpiling tyres can give rise to major fires.<br />

Another additional environmental benefit might be assumed to be the increased takeup<br />

<strong>of</strong> retreaded tyres over new tyres. This, however, has not been quantified as yet. In<br />

any case, the retreaded tyre market is strongly influenced by the price <strong>of</strong> purchasing<br />

primary tyres, and these have become more competitive over the last decade.<br />

Table 29-2 demonstrates the performance <strong>of</strong> the Danish product charge from 1995-<br />

2000. Set against a target <strong>of</strong> an 80% collection rate, the scheme appears to have<br />

achieved and bettered its target rate from 1995-2000. Table 29-3 below highlights<br />

how collected materials have been dealt with.<br />

Table 29-2: Performance <strong>of</strong> the Danish Product Charge 1995 - 2000<br />

Used tyres covered by<br />

the scheme (tonnes)<br />

Collected tyres<br />

(tonnes)<br />

512<br />

29/09/09<br />

2nd 2nd 2nd half<br />

half<br />

1995<br />

1995<br />

1996 1996 1997 1997 1998 1998 1999 1999 2000<br />

2000<br />

8,725 16,705 18,405 19,378 19,816 34,776<br />

7,600 12,670 17,229 16,926 17,314 34,418<br />

Collection Rate (%) 87% 76% 94% 87% 87% 99%<br />

Source: Adapted from:<br />

www2.mst.dk/common/Udgivramme/Frame.asp?http://www2.mst.dk/udgiv/publications/2002/87-<br />

7972-027-7/html/kap03_eng.htm<br />

29.6 Implementation Costs<br />

Again, as most schemes are over 10 years old, information on the implementation<br />

costs for each scheme has been unavailable for this study. Implementation costs <strong>of</strong><br />

the policy are dependent on the scale and remit <strong>of</strong> the scheme chosen.


Considering the impact on the consumer, authorities who have implemented a charge<br />

previously have kept the charge below €4 for each tyre. To the extent that in many<br />

schemes, revenue is used to fund the collection and recycling/recovery <strong>of</strong> tyres, this<br />

would seem to be an indication <strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> ensuring adequate treatment takes<br />

place. Evidently, this revenue must also cover costs for administration <strong>of</strong> the scheme.<br />

29.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The main aim <strong>of</strong> many product charges on tyres is to promote the alternative use <strong>of</strong><br />

waste tyres and to encourage technical change and innovation. In many cases,<br />

alternative products are created from waste tyres, some <strong>of</strong> which include:<br />

513<br />

� Retreading <strong>of</strong> tyres (reuse);<br />

� Conversion into carpet underlay;<br />

� Conversion into a s<strong>of</strong>t cushioning material for children's play areas;<br />

� Reprocessed into rubber mats and other goods; and<br />

� De-vulcanised and re-converted into rubber.<br />

Examining the exact change in a particular country can be difficult. Table 29-3 shows<br />

the broad uses <strong>of</strong> collected tyres in Denmark from 1995-2000. It can be shown that<br />

as the supply <strong>of</strong> tyres has increased, the majority <strong>of</strong> tyres have been converted in to<br />

rubber powder, or incinerated. There has also been a relatively constant level <strong>of</strong> tyre<br />

retreading undertaken during this period, representing a declining share <strong>of</strong> the total.<br />

Table 29-3: Use <strong>of</strong> Collected Tyres in Denmark 1995-2000<br />

Retreading or<br />

continued use (tonnes)<br />

Rubber powder or<br />

incineration (tonnes)<br />

2nd 2nd half<br />

half<br />

1995 1995<br />

1995<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

1996 1996 1997 1997 1998 1998 1999 1999 2000<br />

2000<br />

3,300 5,477 4,581 5,472 3,508 6,690<br />

3,345 6,060 12,648 11,454 13,806 27,728<br />

Source: Adapted from:<br />

www2.mst.dk/common/Udgivramme/Frame.asp?http://www2.mst.dk/udgiv/publications/2002/87-<br />

7972-027-7/html/kap03_eng.htm<br />

29.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

In principle, as with most product taxes, tyre levies could be regressive in their<br />

impact. However, patterns <strong>of</strong> car ownership tend to be such that poorer households<br />

simply do not own cars. In addition, the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the levies concerned is minimal<br />

when compared with the costs <strong>of</strong> cars, though they might be <strong>of</strong> the order 1% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> new tyres.<br />

As regards industry, clearly this may benefit recyclers and re-treaders, as well as, in<br />

the case <strong>of</strong> Denmark, incineration facilities, whilst landfill site operators may lose a<br />

material which is occasionally problematic, though possibly useful in assisting<br />

drainage at the base <strong>of</strong> cells.


29.9 Complementary Policies<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> complementary policies have been used in conjunction with this policy.<br />

The majority focus on disposal outcomes with the most common policy being a landfill<br />

ban. In some cases this is a complete ban on all tyres, however, in some instances it<br />

may only apply to complete tyres. More generally, policies to increase the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

disposal are likely to enhance the likelihood <strong>of</strong> tyres not being disposed <strong>of</strong>, though the<br />

problem <strong>of</strong> storage may still remain.<br />

Another complimentary policy sometimes utilised is a deposit-refund scheme.<br />

29.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

One effect <strong>of</strong> the policy is to make retreated tyres more economically viable than new<br />

tyres. To the extent that these are less environmentally damaging than new tyres,<br />

then the pricing may shift pricing towards a more efficient outcome, though no<br />

example exists <strong>of</strong> a levy being set on the basis <strong>of</strong> estimated externalities.<br />

The measure may encourage the reuse and recycling <strong>of</strong> waste tyres. However, there<br />

has been rather less examination <strong>of</strong> the relative merits <strong>of</strong> landfilling and incinerating<br />

waste tyres. It is not obvious that incineration <strong>of</strong> tyres would be justified on the basis<br />

<strong>of</strong> the balance <strong>of</strong> costs and benefits.<br />

29.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Unknown – no evidence was uncovered or made available.<br />

29.12 Lessons Learned<br />

It appears from our research that many <strong>of</strong> the schemes that started out as simple<br />

product charges have now converted into enhanced producer responsibility schemes.<br />

The main reasoning for this appears to be a need for industry to be involved in the<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> waste tyres. In essence, industry’s involvement is appropriate if “proper<br />

treatment” <strong>of</strong> collected material is to take place. The Texas example provides one<br />

instance where the success <strong>of</strong> the measure in collecting tyres was compromised by<br />

the absence <strong>of</strong> appropriate treatment facilities.<br />

29.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

In principle, the imposition <strong>of</strong> levies presumes the political inclination to implement<br />

these. The collection <strong>of</strong> levies requires an authority to administer the levy, whilst<br />

some body with powers <strong>of</strong> inspection is required to ensure that the levy is being<br />

implemented as planned.<br />

In the schemes where targets are applied, data collection is required, whilst some<br />

sanction might be applicable for non compliance.<br />

514<br />

29/09/09


30.0 Product Taxes - Belgium<br />

30.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Belgium was one <strong>of</strong> the first countries to introduce levies on environmentally<br />

damaging products. The initial aim was to influence producer and consumer<br />

behaviour. Taxes are now levied on:<br />

� beverage packaging,<br />

� disposable cameras and cutlery,<br />

� batteries,<br />

� ink,<br />

� glues and solvents, and<br />

� kitchen foil (see Table 30-1).<br />

However, the tax only applies if there is a reasonable alternative available on the<br />

market. Exemptions are given for disposable cameras, batteries, ink, glues and<br />

solvents where these are separately collected and treated in an environmentallysound<br />

way, or where are collected through a deposit-refund system and effectively reused.<br />

Table 30-1 Ecotax in Belgium<br />

Product Product<br />

Levy<br />

Levy<br />

Re-usable beverage packaging €1.41 /hectolitre<br />

Non re-usable beverage packaging €9.86 /hectolitre<br />

Batteries €0.5 /unit<br />

Disposable cameras €7.44 /unit<br />

Packages <strong>of</strong> certain types <strong>of</strong> glue for<br />

€0.62<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>essional use<br />

for every started quantity <strong>of</strong> 10 litres<br />

Packages <strong>of</strong> certain types <strong>of</strong> ink for<br />

€0.62<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>essional use<br />

for every started quantity <strong>of</strong> 2.5 litres<br />

Packages <strong>of</strong> certain types <strong>of</strong> solvent for<br />

€0.62<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>essional use<br />

for every started quantity <strong>of</strong> 5 litres<br />

Disposable plastic bags €3 /kg<br />

Disposable cutlery €3.6 /kg<br />

Kitchen foil (plastic), etc. €2.7 /kg<br />

Kitchen foil (aluminium), etc. €4.5 /kg<br />

Source: Gewone wet van 16 juli 1993 tot vervollediging van de federale staatsstructuur, Boek III<br />

Milieutaksen<br />

30.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

The initial aim <strong>of</strong> the policy was to influence producer and consumer behaviour.<br />

However, the ecotax policy in Belgium has suffered considerable teething problems<br />

mainly due to political disputes and, as a result, has had to be adapted on several<br />

occasions. The levies were first introduced in the legislation on the reform <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Belgian state. In order to achieve a two thirds majority, which is needed in Belgium to<br />

realise a state reform, the Flemish and Walloon green parties have requested the<br />

515<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


introduction <strong>of</strong> the ecotax. When the state structure was finalised, the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the ecotax was postponed and the measures were weakened<br />

somewhat, as the green parties did not constitute any part <strong>of</strong> the ruling majority.<br />

Levies have been applied with some caution in order not to upset unduly the producer<br />

sectors, and so as not to increase costs to the consumer too dramatically.<br />

The federal ecotax law introduced an environmental tax on 6 product groups:<br />

beverage packaging, single use cameras, batteries, industrial packaging containing<br />

inks, glues and solvents. Initially pesticides, plant based pharmaceuticals, and paper<br />

and cardboard were included as well. However, beverage packaging and paper and<br />

cardboard were initially exempt on the condition that strict recycling targets were met<br />

by industry.<br />

In 2003, the exemption for disposable beverage packaging came to an end and the<br />

concept <strong>of</strong> an eco-premium was introduced to generate a sufficient price difference<br />

between reusable and non-reusable packaging. Re-usable packaging enjoyed a VAT<br />

reduction from 21% to 6%, resulting in a lower price for the consumers.<br />

In 2005, the VAT differential was abolished and since 2006, all beverage packaging<br />

(including re-usable packaging) has been the subject <strong>of</strong> a levy, although the levy for<br />

re-usable packaging is considerably lower, at €1.4 per hectolitre re-usable packaging,<br />

than the levy for non re-usable packaging, at €9.9 per hectolitre.<br />

In 2007 environmental levies were introduced for products that cause exaggerated<br />

CO2 emissions in their production process. The measure was considered by the public<br />

as a way to solve problems in the national budget <strong>of</strong> 2008 and not as an<br />

environmental measure, as the taxes were not expected to shift consumption<br />

patterns. It was therefore withdrawn, except for taxes applied to some more symbolic<br />

and visible issues such as plastic bags, single use cutlery and household foil, where<br />

there is expected to be an effect on the market.<br />

30.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The federal government is the only competent authority for product regulation and<br />

taxes. In the Ordinary Law <strong>of</strong> 1993 on Changing the Belgian State Structure,<br />

regulating the ecotax, reference is made to recycling targets and acceptable waste<br />

treatment methods, referring to the independent waste legislation in the three<br />

Belgian regions. 609<br />

The ecotax law needs to be implemented by Royal Decisions and Ministerial<br />

Decisions. The Decisions need to be endorsed mutually by the Minister <strong>of</strong> Finances<br />

609 Gewone wet van 16 juli 1993 tot vervollediging van de federale staatsstructuur, Boek III<br />

Milieutaksen.<br />

516<br />

29/09/09


and the Minister <strong>of</strong> Economic Affairs. For some issues supplementary endorsement is<br />

requested by the Minister <strong>of</strong> Environment or by the Minister <strong>of</strong> Public Health. 610<br />

The decision on which products are to be submitted to the ecotax is taken by the full<br />

federal Belgian government, presided by the prime minister. This partly explains the<br />

difficult genesis <strong>of</strong> the ecotax law.<br />

The collection <strong>of</strong> ecotaxes is the responsibility <strong>of</strong> the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Finance, <strong>Department</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> Customs and Excise Duties. The ecotax is considered to be an excise duty.<br />

Maintenance <strong>of</strong> the scheme is the responsibility <strong>of</strong> the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Finance.<br />

30.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The following reports are <strong>of</strong> particular relevance:<br />

� A. Heyerick, B. Mazijn and R. Doom (2003) Study in preparation <strong>of</strong> the evaluation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the federal environment-oriented production policy, Final report, Centrum voor<br />

duurzame ontwikkeling, University <strong>of</strong> Ghent, 2003.<br />

� R. Patesson (2001) Beverage packaging and containers, survey conducted with<br />

Belgian families –survey with across-the-border purchasers: The most important<br />

results, Université Libre de Bruxelles, CREATIC-CPSO.<br />

30.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

30.5.1 General Environmental Benefits<br />

30.5.1.1 Evaluation<br />

The impact <strong>of</strong> the ecotax on consumer behaviour remains unclear. A study<br />

undertaken in Wallonia regarding packaging/container methods used for milk and<br />

water products (2003) found that a large majority <strong>of</strong> the respondents (> 90%) were<br />

prepared to switch over to more eco-friendly packaging and containers at a price<br />

differential <strong>of</strong> €0.20. However, it should be kept in mind that this refers only to<br />

expressed preferences, not to actual consumer behaviour.<br />

Another survey arrived at the opposite conclusion, reporting that only a limited<br />

number <strong>of</strong> families would be prepared to change their consumption habits where a<br />

relative price differential existed between re-usable packaging/containers and<br />

disposable packaging/containers. 611 Other studies conducted on the topic <strong>of</strong> the ecopremium<br />

also appear to demonstrate that the levy has not been capable <strong>of</strong><br />

significantly influencing consumer behaviour. For instance one study revealed that<br />

610 It should be considered that the Belgian federal Minister <strong>of</strong> Environment has only limited<br />

competences; on product standards (eg pesticides) and on waste transit. The majority <strong>of</strong> competences<br />

are attributed to the three regional ministers <strong>of</strong> environment.<br />

611 R. Patesson (2001) Beverage packaging and containers, survey conducted with Belgian families –<br />

survey with across-the-border purchasers: The most important results, Université Libre de Bruxelles,<br />

CREATIC-CPSO.<br />

517<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


the sale <strong>of</strong> water in glass bottles dropped by almost one percent; for s<strong>of</strong>t drinks, the<br />

reduction was half <strong>of</strong> one percent, indicating a marginal impact.<br />

30.5.1.2 Choice <strong>of</strong> the Submitted Products<br />

An environmental rationale for the choice <strong>of</strong> product subject to an ecotax is not<br />

always clear. As explained above, the introduction <strong>of</strong> the ecotaxes has known a rather<br />

turbulent legislative history, where competing interests and changing political<br />

configurations have played an important role. The products submitted to the ecotax<br />

tended to be rather visible, mainly household or consumer oriented products, usually<br />

linked to a well known waste issue. They do correspond, in large part, with the waste<br />

types that were defined as priority waste streams in the process <strong>of</strong> the fifth<br />

environmental action programme. The result is a set <strong>of</strong> waste streams subject to the<br />

ecotax for which also European legislation, and especially EPR mechanisms, have<br />

been established later (such as packaging and packaging waste and batteries). A<br />

more scientific approach, with an exercise to prioritise waste streams in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental impact, could be useful either in the definition <strong>of</strong> waste streams for<br />

which a take-back obligation should be implemented, or for which an ecotax would be<br />

beneficial.<br />

30.5.1.3 Sales Evolution <strong>of</strong> Products Submitted to Ecotaxes<br />

It is statistically not possible to prove a relationship between sales figures <strong>of</strong> products<br />

and the effects <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> ecotaxes. However, some trends can be<br />

observed in which the ecotax might have played a role.<br />

FOST-Plus shows that the quantity <strong>of</strong> single use packaging is still increasing, but<br />

suggests that a decoupling between this increase and the growth in the economy has<br />

taken place between 1995 and 2006. Figure 30-1 shows that the amount <strong>of</strong> single<br />

use packaging increased in the Belgian market by 55, 000 tonnes over this period. A<br />

large part <strong>of</strong> the single use household packaging consists <strong>of</strong> beverage packaging<br />

submitted to ecotax. An important year is 2004, when the exemption from ecotax for<br />

beverage packaging was abolished. This coincides with the stabilisation <strong>of</strong> the market<br />

<strong>of</strong> single use packaging (see Figure 30-1), though this does not necessarily prove a<br />

causal relationship between the two. It might simply suggest some support for any<br />

ongoing measures to encourage use <strong>of</strong> reusable packaging.<br />

518<br />

29/09/09


Figure 30-1: Market Data on Single Use Packaging Expressed in kTon Packaging (data<br />

FOST-Plus)<br />

Translated: ‘Verpakkigen’ is ‘Total Packaging and ‘BBP’ is ‘GDP’<br />

The volume <strong>of</strong> collected batteries is represented in Figure 15-4 in chapter 15.5.3.2.<br />

Diane Roos mentions in the electronic periodical Retail 612 the following figures on the<br />

evolution <strong>of</strong> markets for single use and for rechargeable batteries for 2007:<br />

519<br />

� In 2007 more than 22 million single use batteries were sold in Belgium. These<br />

were mostly alkaline batteries (only 115,000 zinc-carbon batteries were sold);<br />

� The market for single use batteries shows a slight decline <strong>of</strong> – 4.8% in volume<br />

terms. By value, the market increased by 3.1%;<br />

� The total Belgian market for single use batteries is 38.5 million euro;<br />

� The market for rechargeable batteries is clearly growing (by 8.1%) in value;<br />

and<br />

� The total Belgian sales <strong>of</strong> rechargeable batteries are 6.51 million euro.<br />

These figures do not necessarily indicate the success <strong>of</strong> the eco-tax since this may<br />

reflect trends for which the eco-tax alone was not responsible. No figures on the<br />

Belgian market evolution <strong>of</strong> disposable cameras has been found.<br />

612 http://www.convenience.be/dossiers/tabid/1172/default.aspx?_vs=0_N&id=ERT0126n01.mth<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


30.5.1.4 Destination <strong>of</strong> the Revenue Collected.<br />

The ecotax is an excise levy for which the revenue is not ear-marked for<br />

environmental or other purposes. The revenues are destined for the Belgian federal<br />

treasury. For this reason, the regulatory aspect <strong>of</strong> the tax and the lack <strong>of</strong> ear-marking<br />

makes that the instrument most attractive in times when budgetary shortages<br />

emerge and increasing other taxes becomes unpopular.<br />

30.5.2 Links with Producer Responsibility<br />

Ecotaxes can be avoided for batteries and for single use cameras if a functioning<br />

collection system can be set up that reaches specific targets in terms <strong>of</strong> collection<br />

efficiency, and ensures that the treatment <strong>of</strong> the waste takes place in facilities which<br />

are considered to deploy Best Available Techniques, as defined on a regional basis.<br />

30.5.2.1 Single Use Cameras<br />

For single use cameras the levy <strong>of</strong> €7.44 /camera can be avoided if a collection<br />

system ensures that at least 80% <strong>of</strong> the cameras collected by the photo development<br />

laboratories are reused, or recycled in Belgium, or abroad.<br />

30.5.2.2 Batteries and BEBAT<br />

For batteries 613 the levy <strong>of</strong> €0.5 /battery can be avoided if a deposit system is<br />

applied, or if a collection system is already established. No deposit system has been<br />

realised in Belgium. The collection system was established right from the outset <strong>of</strong><br />

the ecotax legislation, following the establishment <strong>of</strong> BEBAT (see Section 30.5.2.2).<br />

Ecotax and the later imposed EPR and take-back obligation, are effectively reinforcing<br />

each other (see also Sections 15.3.3, 15.5.3 and 15.6.3). The ecotax was introduced<br />

in 1993, while the take back obligation dates from 1997.<br />

Batteries were to be exempted from the ecotax once a (first voluntary) collection and<br />

recycling scheme was set up, under the condition that the system had to be financed<br />

by the battery industry, and that following target percentages for recycling had to be<br />

met:<br />

520<br />

� For the year 2002: 60 %;<br />

� For the year 2003: 62.5 %; and<br />

� For the year 2004 and subsequent years: 65 %<br />

All batteries need to be treated in accordance with best available techniques for<br />

disposal or recycling, in accordance with the regional legislation. Accordance with the<br />

take-back obligations included in VLAREA and in the MBO (see Section 15.3.3) also<br />

needs to be undertaken. The collection percentages are raised to 75% and a recycling<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> 65% is introduced.<br />

613 Excl accumulators in cars.<br />

29/09/09


In order to achieve these targets, the battery industry set up a non-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation<br />

called BEBAT to co-ordinate the collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> batteries, and to ensure<br />

that the target percentages were reached. The financing <strong>of</strong> the 'collection and<br />

recycling contribution' is paid by members <strong>of</strong> the organisation (i.e. battery producers<br />

and distributors). This contribution is passed on to the consumers through a price<br />

increase.<br />

Prior to the voluntary collection system for batteries in Belgium, only a small<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> batteries were recycled. The public waste companies considered them<br />

to be hazardous waste, and consumers were supposed to collect them separately,<br />

but there were no incentives in place. Of the small number <strong>of</strong> batteries that were<br />

collected separately, only the nickel-cadmium batteries were being recycled.<br />

According to BEBAT, the efficiency <strong>of</strong> the BEBAT collection system currently stands at<br />

86 % (88.5 % in the Flemish region).<br />

30.6 Implementation Costs<br />

Ecotaxes translate into income for the government and represent an expense for the<br />

consumer or for the producer. These may lead to a relatively cost-effective<br />

instrument. This, however, relies on the condition that there exists an efficient<br />

collection system for the tax; otherwise the whole system will turn into a costineffective<br />

instrument for both the government and the enterprises. 614<br />

30.6.1 How the Cost <strong>of</strong> Collection Relates to Revenues Generated<br />

The revenues <strong>of</strong> the ecotax are principally not related to the costs <strong>of</strong> the collection.<br />

Both the ecotax and the cost <strong>of</strong> the collection have to be carried by the involved<br />

companies. The ecotax has to be paid by the producer <strong>of</strong> the product. The collection<br />

cost has to be paid by the generator <strong>of</strong> the waste. Both apply unless the producer has<br />

submitted to an accompanying take-back obligation.<br />

The ecotax is indirectly connected to the collection costs in the cases where an<br />

exemption is allowed for those wastes for which a well- performing collection system<br />

is set up (e.g. batteries, single use cameras, pr<strong>of</strong>essional packaging <strong>of</strong> glue, ink,<br />

solvents). In case <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional packaging <strong>of</strong> certain fluids, the concept <strong>of</strong> a<br />

‘packaging credit’ is introduced. This is a system in which an amount is credited by<br />

the seller on the invoice <strong>of</strong> the client, equal to the real costs for the collection and<br />

legal treatment <strong>of</strong> the waste by a waste collector appointed by the seller. When a<br />

system <strong>of</strong> packaging credit is in place, an exemption from the ecotax obligation can<br />

be obtained.<br />

30.7 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

An ecotax might be considered to be a measure with the potential for regressive<br />

impacts: low-income individuals or large families might be more affected than those<br />

614 OVAM (2007) Analysis <strong>of</strong> innovative environmental policy instruments towards the realisation <strong>of</strong><br />

environmentally responsible production and consumption.<br />

521<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


with higher disposable incomes, although this also depends upon consumer<br />

behaviour. The tax can be avoided through changing consumption patterns, and it is<br />

important to note that the ecotax applies to products only where there are viable<br />

substitutes. Indeed, it may be cheaper, in the longer-term, to pay for more durable<br />

products, or alternatives having other characteristics, but here, the question is more<br />

one <strong>of</strong> cashflow / access to credit (and the cost <strong>of</strong> credit).<br />

There is some limited risk <strong>of</strong> an increase in across-the-border purchases, resulting in<br />

an economic loss for Belgian producers / distributors. However, the products and<br />

sums introduced make it very unlikely that journeys would, arguably, be made<br />

specifically for this purpose.<br />

Some industry sectors could be seen to benefit, at the margin, relative to others. For<br />

example, disposable cameras would have become marginally more expensive, but<br />

these shifts are expected to have been marginal, with the demise <strong>of</strong> disposable<br />

cameras being far more bound to the rise in the phenomenon <strong>of</strong> digital cameras than<br />

to the ecotax.<br />

30.8 Complementary Policies<br />

30.8.1 Take-Back Obligations and <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programmes<br />

While the direct effect <strong>of</strong> the ecotax regulation is not always clear, it has been the<br />

driving force for the implementation <strong>of</strong> different EPR and take-back systems. The<br />

strength <strong>of</strong> the ecotax can be found in the possibility to link an exemption with the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> a well-performing collection system.<br />

EPR systems require a well-performing collection system. Driven by the ecotax,<br />

industry has organised itself into bodies to realise and finance the collection logistics<br />

for their products. BEBAT, as mentioned above, is a clear example, as it originated as<br />

an industry initiative. A few years before the EPR, the take-back obligation and the<br />

MBO on batteries came into force (see Section 15.3.3). On packaging waste, no<br />

exemption procedure for improved collection was introduced, and thus the link with<br />

EPR systems is less obvious. The ecotax system has nevertheless lead to prevention<br />

programmes and the stimulus <strong>of</strong> reusable packaging, which has a much lower ecotax<br />

than non reusable packaging. Some exemption procedures for packaging waste<br />

proved counter-productive and have been abolished. See also Section 30.10 for<br />

evasion mechanisms for the price differentials.<br />

30.8.2 Collection Targets<br />

Ecotax legislation imposes targets for collection systems that could lead to an<br />

exemption <strong>of</strong> the ecotax for certain, above mentioned, waste streams. No targets are<br />

imposed on recycling or treatment <strong>of</strong> the waste, but reference is made to the<br />

Regional legislation and the regionally defined best practices that have to be<br />

applied. 615 The reason why the legislation on ecotaxes does not include explicit<br />

615 Except for single use cameras where a recycling percentage <strong>of</strong> 80% is imposed.<br />

522<br />

29/09/09


ecycling targets is partly linked to the fact that the complex state structure <strong>of</strong><br />

Belgium, where taxes are Federal competence, and recycling and waste policy are<br />

exclusively Regional competences.<br />

30.8.3 Differential Tariffs (DIFTAR)<br />

DIFTAR (see Sections 8.0 through 10.0) is a method to stimulate especially private<br />

persons to sort their household waste into different fractions. This does enhance<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> separate collection schemes. There is, however, no link with ecotax,<br />

because ecotax exemptions for better collected waste streams are applied on<br />

batteries and pr<strong>of</strong>essional packaging <strong>of</strong> certain liquids. Both streams are not covered<br />

by the usual DIFTAR regimes. Batteries belong to the hazardous household waste<br />

scheme for which a separate sorting obligation exists independent <strong>of</strong> different<br />

tariffication, and the pr<strong>of</strong>essional packaging does not belong to the household waste<br />

fraction.<br />

30.8.4 Information Campaigns and Public Awareness<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> ecotaxes needs to be coupled to an extensive information<br />

campaign. Awareness raising and education are very important factors to create<br />

support for the policy.<br />

30.9 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> eco-taxes is to improve the efficiency <strong>of</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> markets by<br />

internalising externalities associated with products. However, few taxes are set by<br />

direct reference to the externalities <strong>of</strong> the products themselves. The rates are set<br />

based on the desired regulatory effect <strong>of</strong> discouraging undesired products or waste.<br />

The level is based upon the desire to intervene in the market, but again referring to<br />

the awkward development <strong>of</strong> the legislation, political horse-trading could not have<br />

been completely excluded. In addition, the ecotax is not applied where certain targets<br />

are met, so that the aim might be taken to have been delivery <strong>of</strong> the outcomes which<br />

an ecotax might have achieved had it been implemented.<br />

30.10 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The production sector can put a spoke in the ecotax / eco-premium wheel, as<br />

demonstrated by an example taken from Coca-Cola. Coca-Cola introduced a price<br />

increase for re-usable bottles, whereby the relative price differential between, on the<br />

one hand, re-usable bottles, and on the other, single use PET-bottles and cans was<br />

erased.<br />

An increase in cross-border purchases may possibly be occurring, but no statistics are<br />

available to confirm or reject this.<br />

30.11 Lessons Learned<br />

A sufficiently large levy or, in other words, an adequate price differential between<br />

regular products and their eco-friendly variants is crucial. However, the optimal price<br />

differentiation between eco-friendly products and less eco-friendly products still<br />

needs to be determined.<br />

523<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


In the implementation <strong>of</strong> the regulation, a ‘trial and error’ method to determine this<br />

optimal price is clearly not a good system for industry and for the distribution sector<br />

since the sector needs to have sufficient security about the required investments. If<br />

such a trial and error method was to be used, it might be more preferable for this to<br />

be used in the context <strong>of</strong> targets for behavioural shifts.<br />

Finally, it would be preferable to have an objective basis for the introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

ecotaxes. The choice <strong>of</strong> products has not always been rational, but neither has<br />

opposition to the choice.<br />

30.12 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

It is important to develop an optimised mix with other instruments like recycling<br />

targets or EPR-mechanisms. There is clearly a ‘mix’ in Belgium, but it is not clear that<br />

this optimised.<br />

Ecotax and the possibility to obtain an exemption on the ecotax can serve as a driving<br />

force for useful industry initiatives. Industry must be <strong>of</strong>fered a possibility to find a<br />

constructive way to avoid the taxes which they probably will not back, instead <strong>of</strong> the<br />

less constructive ways <strong>of</strong> policy influencing or lobbying, or the establishment <strong>of</strong><br />

evasion techniques (see the example for Coca-Cola in Section 30.10).<br />

It is likely to be useful to clearly explain to industry what the ecotax will be used for.<br />

Full transparency on the way the rates are calculated might also be desirable. Some<br />

stronger rationale for the ecotax would also improve acceptance.<br />

Awareness raising and education are very important factors to create support for the<br />

policy from consumers.<br />

524<br />

29/09/09


31.0 Plastic Bag Bans – <strong>International</strong><br />

31.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

This policy seeks to prohibit the production, distribution and use <strong>of</strong> polythene bags –<br />

known commonly as plastic bags. The raison d'être for the need <strong>of</strong> ban can vary from<br />

country to country or region to region, but most commonly, a ban is implemented due<br />

to adverse environmental damage imposed upon landscapes. Issues surrounding soil<br />

degradation, loss <strong>of</strong> soil fertility and health impacts are <strong>of</strong>ten cited as reasons for<br />

implementing bans. 616 In addition, plastic bags are considered by some to be an<br />

unsightly component <strong>of</strong> litter.<br />

Implementation <strong>of</strong> plastic bag bans can vary widely depending on which<br />

authority/regulator is authorising the ban. In some instances, authorities will only<br />

have the power to implement prohibitions in the distribution <strong>of</strong> bags. These tend to<br />

be undertaken by municipalities on the city-wide or town-wide scale. In some<br />

instances, these are community driven and operate under a voluntary code <strong>of</strong><br />

practice.<br />

More comprehensive bans, which include the manufacture, distribution and use <strong>of</strong><br />

bags, are most <strong>of</strong>ten undertaken by nation-states. In most instances, bans are<br />

subject to a number <strong>of</strong> exemptions. These include exemptions for products that<br />

require polythene packaging because no alternative materials are available on the<br />

market (particularly healthcare goods).<br />

This policy seeks to remove polythene bags from the collected waste stream, and<br />

prior to that, from streets and drains. The main actors in the economy affected by the<br />

ban are the manufacturers and retailers <strong>of</strong> bags.<br />

31.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

Bangladesh was the first nation-state to impose a nationwide ban on plastic bags on<br />

1 st March 2002. 617 Other small nation-states have subsequently imposed bans.<br />

These include:<br />

525<br />

� Bhutan<br />

� Rwanda; and<br />

� Eritrea.<br />

A complete ban on the production, distribution and use <strong>of</strong> plastic bags is rare.<br />

However, there is a trend for more and more countries to consider outright bans. For<br />

616 http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/south_asia/1329600.stm consulted August 2008.<br />

617 Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment and Forests, Bangladesh (2008) Major <strong>Policy</strong> Initiatives, consulted October<br />

2008 http://www.doe-bd.org/policy.html<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


example, both Italy and France have proposed to ban plastic bags in 2010. 618 Wales<br />

is known to be considering a ban.<br />

Elsewhere, bans have been imposed on a state-wide, city-wide or town-wide basis.<br />

These tend to be bans on the distribution <strong>of</strong> plastic bags, as these are the only<br />

powers available to the relevant authorities. Some <strong>of</strong> the most high pr<strong>of</strong>ile cases<br />

include;<br />

526<br />

� San Francisco, USA;<br />

� Coles Bay, Tasmania, Australia;<br />

� Maharashtra, India;<br />

� Leaf Rapids, Manitoba, Canada; and<br />

� Modbury, Devon, UK<br />

In Bangladesh and other countries faced with monsoon rains, plastic bags are<br />

believed to cause havoc with drainage systems. In some instances, plastic bags have<br />

been identified as a key cause <strong>of</strong> urban flooding. Specifically in Bangladesh, it is<br />

believed that plastic bags contributed to the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the 1998 floods, where<br />

75% <strong>of</strong> the country was submerged.<br />

31.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

In Bangladesh, the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment is the regulator <strong>of</strong> the ban.<br />

Implementation <strong>of</strong> legislation was keyed by the Cabinet, via the Ministry <strong>of</strong><br />

Environment and Forests. <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> the policy is directed by the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

Environment. Elsewhere a similar model is utilised.<br />

31.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

31.4.1 Bangladesh<br />

Through the Sustainable Environment <strong>Management</strong> Programme (SEMP), a task force<br />

was commissioned to study the effects <strong>of</strong> phasing out polythene bags. The task force<br />

fashioned a report which outlined the implications <strong>of</strong> imposing a ban. After a change<br />

in government in 2001, a ban was imposed in Dhaka City on 1 st January 2002.<br />

Within three months, the ban had been extended to the whole country. 619<br />

618 http://www.endseurope.com/11239 and http://www.rte.ie/news/2008/0527/plasticbags.html<br />

consulted October 2008.<br />

619 Bangladesh Centre for Advanced Studies (2006) A Step Forward to Promoting Environmentally<br />

Sustainable Development in Bangladesh, available at http://ekh.unep.org/?q=node/2220<br />

29/09/09


31.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

Environmental outcomes targeted by bans on plastic bags include the following:<br />

527<br />

� To reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> polythene in the waste stream;<br />

� To reduce the possibility <strong>of</strong> plastic bags blocking drains and exacerbating<br />

flooding in urban areas; and<br />

� To reduce the presence <strong>of</strong> plastic bags in litter; plastic bags are highly visible<br />

components <strong>of</strong> litter and are very much associated in the public mind with the<br />

problem <strong>of</strong> litter pollution.<br />

Quantification <strong>of</strong> these effects has not been forthcoming but the impact in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

overall reduction in municipal waste is anticipated to be minimal (due to the low<br />

relative weight <strong>of</strong> plastic bags in the total waste stream and substitution by other<br />

carriers).<br />

31.6 Implementation Costs<br />

Unknown – no evidence was uncovered or made available.<br />

Costs may include compensation to industry involved in making and distributing<br />

plastic bags.<br />

31.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

In order to replace polythene, suitable alternative materials are required. The most<br />

common <strong>of</strong> these alternatives that have emerged as substitutes are jute and paper<br />

bags.<br />

In Bangladesh, it was found that jute bags were the best alternative to polythene. Jute<br />

is grown throughout Bangladesh, and the Bengal delta plain is considered to be one<br />

<strong>of</strong> the world’s finest growing areas.<br />

31.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

None found. However, it might be expected that in Bangladesh, for example, the jute<br />

industry may have been a major beneficiary <strong>of</strong> a ban.<br />

31.9 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> the policy was to eliminate specific bags identified as having potential to<br />

do harm, and in Bangladesh’s case, significant damage. The ban does not work<br />

through the price mechanism per se.<br />

The policy has led to more alternative bags being used in the market. These are more<br />

expensive to purchase, but tend to be longer lasting, although plastic bags may have<br />

had additional uses. The alternatives are considered to be more environmentally<br />

friendly and importantly, are locally sourced. The net effect might be some increased<br />

cost to customers, though in the round, the net effect is not entirely clear. Even “free<br />

bags” must incur some cost somewhere in the distribution system, so the issue is one<br />

<strong>of</strong> relative cost, taking in to account re-usability.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


31.10 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Upon enacting the ban in Bangladesh there have been some problems with illegal<br />

polythene bags entering the country and being used by consumers. No evidence is<br />

available <strong>of</strong> measures that have been taken in order to combat this issue.<br />

31.11 Lessons Learned<br />

Evaluation studies assessing the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the ban and from which lessons<br />

learned could be drawn are not available, despite the fact that the ban is no longer in<br />

its infancy.<br />

528<br />

29/09/09


32.0 Levy on <strong>Waste</strong> Paints - <strong>International</strong><br />

32.1 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

Across North America, a levy on new paints is applied in a number <strong>of</strong> localities.<br />

Specifically a charge can be found in California in the USA and in British Columbia,<br />

Alberta, Saskatchewan, Nova Scotia and New Brunswick in Canada.<br />

The reasoning for implementing a charge varies in each area. In California, the ec<strong>of</strong>ee<br />

on spray cans has been in existence since 1990 and is used to fund graffiti cleanup<br />

activities. In Canada the fee is applied to whole host <strong>of</strong> household paints and is<br />

collected as part <strong>of</strong> ‘enhanced producer responsibility schemes’ or ‘extended<br />

producer responsibility schemes’. These schemes differ in their operation in that, as<br />

inferred by their name, a group <strong>of</strong> producers take responsibility for the scheme.<br />

Collection <strong>of</strong> the revenue is operated through a not-for-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation owned and<br />

operated by industry.<br />

The reasoning for creating the schemes in Canada is also different than that in<br />

California. As highlighted in the ‘Greener Homes, Cleaner Communities’ report in<br />

1994, Canadian householders were unable to access a sufficient network <strong>of</strong> paint<br />

collection facilities. This led to the development <strong>of</strong> the regulatory framework for<br />

enhanced producer responsibility schemes where the polluter pays principle was<br />

implemented.<br />

32.1.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> minor variations in the type, use and magnitude <strong>of</strong> the charge<br />

in the different states and provinces. Some <strong>of</strong> these are outlined in Table 32-1.<br />

Table 32-1: Characteristics <strong>of</strong> Different Charging Regimes for Paints<br />

100 ml to<br />

250 ml<br />

251 ml to 1<br />

litre<br />

1.01 litres to<br />

5 litres<br />

5.01 litres to<br />

23 litres<br />

Aerosol paint<br />

(any size)<br />

529<br />

British<br />

British<br />

Columbia<br />

Columbia<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Alberta Alberta Saskatch<br />

Saskatch<br />

ewan ewan<br />

ewan<br />

New<br />

New<br />

Brunswick Brunswick<br />

Brunswick<br />

Nova Nova<br />

Nova<br />

Scotia<br />

Scotia<br />

California<br />

California<br />

€0.06 €0.06 €0.06 €0.12 €0.06 N/A<br />

€0.15 €0.15 €0.15 €0.22 €0.15 N/A<br />

€0.25 €0.31 €0.25 €0.43 €0.31 N/A<br />

€0.62 €0.62 €0.62 €0.92 €0.62 N/A<br />

€0.06 €0.06 €0.06 €0.12 €0.06 €0.07


In addition to variations in the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the charge, there are also variations in<br />

the visibility <strong>of</strong> the charge. In some areas the ‘eco-fee’ is visible and can be identified<br />

by consumers. There are, however, areas where the fee is hidden and simply<br />

included in the price <strong>of</strong> the paints.<br />

32.1.2 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and <strong>Management</strong><br />

The organisation responsible for the management <strong>of</strong> the charge can vary dependent<br />

on the type <strong>of</strong> scheme implemented.<br />

Where enhanced producer responsibility schemes are utilised, revenue accrued is<br />

usually managed by a not-for-pr<strong>of</strong>it organisation, normally operated by industry. The<br />

organisation is also responsible for facilitating recycling activities by utilising the<br />

revenue accrued through the fund. A selected example follows.<br />

32.1.2.1 Product Care Scheme - Canada<br />

The Product Care scheme is a not-for-pr<strong>of</strong>it producer responsibility scheme which<br />

manages product stewardship programs for household hazardous and special waste<br />

on behalf <strong>of</strong> its members across Canada. The scheme manages stewardship<br />

programs in British Columbia for paint, flammable liquids, pesticides and gasoline,<br />

and in Nova Scotia, Saskatchewan and New Brunswick for paint only. 620<br />

In British Columbia, Product Care was enabled and created as a result <strong>of</strong> the Post-<br />

Consumer Paint Stewardship Program Regulation (British Columbia Regulation.<br />

200/94), which was enacted in 1994 under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act.<br />

The Act requires paint producers take cradle-to-grave responsibility for the<br />

management <strong>of</strong> the products that contribute to the household hazardous waste<br />

stream. To maintain a "level playing field" amongst paint producers, the regulation<br />

was amended on June 26, 1997 to include all paints sold in pressurized containers<br />

(aerosols). In 2004, this regulation was replaced by the Recycling Regulation. 621<br />

32.2 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

In British Columbia, the pre-implementation report ‘Greener Homes, Cleaner<br />

Communities’ noted that legislation would be required to increase the capture in<br />

household hazardous waste, which includes paint. We have been unable to obtain a<br />

copy <strong>of</strong> this report but note that its findings were an important factor in the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> the regulations in British Columbia.<br />

Considering the evaluation studies in British Columbia, Gardner Pinfold Consulting 622<br />

conducted an economic assessment <strong>of</strong> the Product Care scheme in British Columbia.<br />

620 Adapted from: http://productcare.org/about.html [Accessed March 2009]<br />

621 Adapted from http://www.ec.gc.ca/epr/default.asp?lang=En&n=3A0FB78D-1#programdetails<br />

[Accessed March 2009]<br />

622 Gardner Pinfold Consulting (2008) Economic Impacts <strong>of</strong> the BC Recycling Regulation, Report for<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment Environmental Quality Branch. Available at:<br />

http://www.env.gov.bc.ca/epd/recycling/resources/reports/econ.htm<br />

530<br />

29/09/09


The report concluded that total employment generated by recycling paints,<br />

flammables including gasoline and pesticides is estimated at just over 73 FTEs based<br />

on information provided by Product Care.<br />

The collection Depots account for about 68% (50 FTEs). The rest is spread across<br />

Product Care administration (8%, 5 3/4 FTEs), Product Care consolidation plant (18%,<br />

13 FTEs), and transportation (6%, about 4.5 FTEs).<br />

32.3 Environmental Benefits<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> direct environmental benefits associated with the recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

paint. Benefits include avoided contamination and avoided subsequent remedial<br />

clean up costs from improperly disposed products. There are also greenhouse gas<br />

benefits in recycling the paint container, whether it may be steel or plastic.<br />

The policy also provides a number <strong>of</strong> associated environmental benefits. As the<br />

schemes in Canada are managed by producers, it is in their interest to ensure that all<br />

costs associated with the recycling <strong>of</strong> paints are reduced as far as possible (as the<br />

required revenue to cover costs would be reflected in the price <strong>of</strong> goods sold). This<br />

driver has undoubtedly influenced technology innovation/change and aided<br />

additional environmental benefits.<br />

32.4 Implementation Costs<br />

Comprehensive studies on implementation costs have been unable to be found thus<br />

far.<br />

32.5 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Probably, the involvement <strong>of</strong> the paint suppliers in the recycling <strong>of</strong> paint by the use <strong>of</strong><br />

producer responsibility schemes has been a key driver in the innovation towards<br />

production, sale and use more environmentally friendly paint products. We have<br />

been, however, unable to discover any direct evidence linking these factors together<br />

thus far.<br />

32.6 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The impacts <strong>of</strong> the policy are likely to be regressive. Here, it is worth noting that the<br />

levies used to cover costs tend to be proportionately higher for smaller volumes <strong>of</strong><br />

paint. There may be good reasons for this where the costs <strong>of</strong> recovery <strong>of</strong> paints and<br />

the containers are concerned. However, the environmental issues associated with<br />

paints might be expected to be linked to volume if there is a considerable amount <strong>of</strong><br />

unused paint being discarded. On the other hand, if the paint containers are more<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten than not empty, then the charge structure might be appropriate.<br />

In some schemes operating at a community level, old paints are made available to<br />

social projects and low income households to help reduce the costs <strong>of</strong> paint.<br />

32.7 Complementary Policies<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> complementary policies have been used in conjunction with this policy,<br />

most notably the use <strong>of</strong> a producer responsibility scheme. The majority <strong>of</strong> other<br />

531<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


policies focus on disposal outcomes with the most common policy being a landfill<br />

ban.<br />

32.8 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

Section 32.6 highlights some issues related to social and distributional<br />

consequences. There, it was noted that pricing might not necessarily be in line with<br />

expected impacts. As with many policy measures, the pricing probably improves<br />

matters relative to the ‘no policy’ situation, but the pricing is not efficient and few<br />

studies have sought to understand what the externalities associated with the use <strong>of</strong><br />

different paints / the disposal <strong>of</strong> paints might be.<br />

32.9 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Only anecdotal evidence has been provided on evasion and enforcement issues thus<br />

far. Conversations with Product Care in Canada have highlighted only minimal<br />

evasion <strong>of</strong> the scheme. According to Product Care, minimal enforcement is required<br />

to operate the scheme.<br />

32.10 Lessons Learned<br />

Anecdotal evidence suggests that the use <strong>of</strong> enhanced producer responsibility<br />

schemes in Canada have greatly aided the recycling <strong>of</strong> waste paints. Placing these<br />

observations in context, one <strong>of</strong> the fundamental problems with recycling waste paints<br />

in Canada has been the (in)ability <strong>of</strong> householders to access a collection point, which<br />

is largely attributed to the sparsely distributed population <strong>of</strong> the country. The policies<br />

have tended to enhance the prospects for proper collection <strong>of</strong> unused paints and<br />

paint cans at their end <strong>of</strong> life.<br />

32.11 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

As with other producer responsibility mechanisms, key pre-requisites appear to be:<br />

� The political willingness to legislate to deal with the issue; and<br />

� Working with industry to develop an agreed mechanism to ensure the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> adequate infrastructure to address the problem being highlighted.<br />

532<br />

29/09/09


33.0 Circular WPPR 17/08 - Ireland<br />

33.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The Circular WPPR 17/08 on the Implementation <strong>of</strong> Segregated ‘Brown Bin’<br />

Collection for Biowaste and Home Composting was issued on 31 July 2008 to all City<br />

and County Managers. In it, the Minister requests local authorities to -<br />

533<br />

� accelerate the implementation <strong>of</strong> the National Strategy on Biodegradable<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> and in particular the roll-out <strong>of</strong> the ‘brown brown brown bin bin’ bin source-segregated<br />

collection systems for organic waste in order to drive the diversion <strong>of</strong><br />

biodegradable municipal waste from landfill, through -<br />

• Direct provision <strong>of</strong> such services;<br />

• Consultation with the collectors;<br />

• Imposition <strong>of</strong> conditions on <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Permits across each<br />

region;<br />

• Introduction and modification <strong>of</strong> local bye-laws;<br />

• Provision <strong>of</strong> composting/biogas infrastructure;<br />

• Educational Awareness campaigns;<br />

• Targeted enforcement.<br />

� Promote home composting in suitable areas through ongoing awareness and<br />

education/training campaigns, including the provision <strong>of</strong> home composting<br />

units to householders at reduced prices.<br />

It goes on to state that:<br />

The Minister intends to require source segregation <strong>of</strong> commercial<br />

biodegradable waste and local authorities’ waste planning should take<br />

account <strong>of</strong> this.<br />

More specifically, the Circular states:<br />

Local authorities should provide for, as a matter <strong>of</strong> urgency:<br />

� The implementation <strong>of</strong> source-segregated collection for organic waste in<br />

urban areas (i.e. urban agglomerations <strong>of</strong> greater than 1,500 persons –<br />

the Census <strong>of</strong> Population 2006 reports that 61% <strong>of</strong> the population in<br />

Ireland reside in urban areas <strong>of</strong> greater than 1,500 persons);<br />

� The promotion <strong>of</strong> home composting and/or community composting outside<br />

<strong>of</strong> these areas.<br />

33.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The Circular was issued in the wake <strong>of</strong> a growing concern regarding Ireland’s ability to<br />

meet the targets for reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste sent to landfill set<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


out under Article 5 <strong>of</strong> the EU Landfill Directive (see Annex 51.0). It followed the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> a National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy.<br />

33.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

As mentioned above, the Circular was issued 31 July 2008. However, it does not<br />

appear to set a deadline for implementation <strong>of</strong> what is proposed. Indeed, response to<br />

the Circular appears to have been patchy. Some authorities are in the process <strong>of</strong><br />

rolling out brown bin collections, but several authorities and private sector operators<br />

have tended to drag their feet somewhat. The private sector collectors might be<br />

expected to maintain this approach in the absence <strong>of</strong> changes to their collection<br />

permits. Some collectors’ permits have been changed to reflect this Circular.<br />

33.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Key players are expected to be local authorities, since they have the power to<br />

introduce measures, through the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Collection Permit) Regulations<br />

2007, which require collection <strong>of</strong> specific materials, and also, the power to introduce<br />

bye-laws which place obligations on the waste producers (households or businesses)<br />

to segregate specific wastes.<br />

The Regions, <strong>of</strong> which the local authorities are part, are expected to report progress in<br />

annual progress reports submitted to the <strong>Department</strong> regarding their waste<br />

management plans. They are also expected to ensure that they identify capacity (or,<br />

presumably, ensure that such capacity can be provided) where separate collections<br />

are to be introduced.<br />

The EPA is also expected to play a role through disseminating best practice, not least<br />

in the area <strong>of</strong> home composting as part <strong>of</strong> its lead in the National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

programme. It also has a key role in the collection <strong>of</strong> data, although this data tends to<br />

appear a time lag <strong>of</strong> the order one year.<br />

Cré, the Composting Association <strong>of</strong> Ireland, is also expected to play a role since, in<br />

partnership with the Institute <strong>of</strong> Technology Sligo and FÁS, it has developed a training<br />

course aimed at facility operators, regulators, planners/designers, which the Circular<br />

promotes engagement with.<br />

33.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

A key mechanism for monitoring progress would be expected to be the EPA’s National<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Reports and, at present, the annual reports on progress regarding<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the regional waste management plans. However, regarding the<br />

latter, we note that few regions have issued such reports thus far. We also note that<br />

the recommendations in the Main Report include the proposal to effectively do away<br />

with the regions for the purpose <strong>of</strong> waste management planning.<br />

33.6 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

None available (insufficient time elapsed). Even so, anecdotal evidence suggests that<br />

progress has been slow. This is not entirely unexpected. Both local authorities and<br />

534<br />

29/09/09


private sector operators incur costs when unplanned changes to services are<br />

introduced and so even where the actors involved are willing participants in the<br />

change, there may be reluctance to make the switch quite as quickly as might be<br />

desired. Finally, we note that there appears to be no sanction proposed for<br />

application to those City and County Managers who do not follow the Circular’s<br />

recommendations, let alone to those private sector operators who might be reluctant<br />

to change their collection service before they have to.<br />

33.7 Environmental Benefits<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> the Circular is to ensure that biodegradable waste which might otherwise<br />

be landfilled is dealt with through alternative means. In environmental terms, reports<br />

elsewhere suggest that the net benefits <strong>of</strong> such an approach will depend considerably<br />

on: 623<br />

535<br />

� The design <strong>of</strong> the collection system;<br />

� The choice <strong>of</strong> treatment system for collected biowaste; and<br />

� The charging system applied in the context <strong>of</strong> the collection system used.<br />

The reason environmental benefits may not be secured by the policy relate to the way<br />

in which the two principal fractions <strong>of</strong> the targeted organic waste – food waste and<br />

garden waste – behave when they are targeted for collection. Studies in the UK and<br />

elsewhere highlight the potential for considerable quantities <strong>of</strong> garden waste to be<br />

collected where garden waste services are <strong>of</strong>fered free <strong>of</strong> charge. One report refers to<br />

this as the problem <strong>of</strong> a ‘latent garden waste fraction’, lending itself to the possibility<br />

that collected organic waste increases significantly in tonnage terms.<br />

Data in Figure 33-1 shows two years <strong>of</strong> total waste arisings tonnage data for a UK<br />

authority where a free garden waste collection service was put in place. In our<br />

experience, this is a typical outcome in temperate countries such as the UK and<br />

Ireland. The difference between the two lines <strong>of</strong> data represents the quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

garden waste that was separately collected. The service was trialled for a limited<br />

number <strong>of</strong> households in the first year before being provided to all households in the<br />

second year. Several important characteristics <strong>of</strong> garden waste generation and the<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> collection services can be observed in the data:<br />

• Firstly, the impact <strong>of</strong> providing a new and free collection service is seen to<br />

increase total waste arisings; this can largely be attributed to a reduction in<br />

home composting and a potential encouragement <strong>of</strong> harvesting a latent<br />

garden waste fraction (i.e. the new outlet for garden waste brings<br />

additional material into the waste management system that was either not<br />

created or previously managed at source – material from hedge cutting for<br />

instance);<br />

623 Eunomia (2007) Managing Biowastes from Households in the UK: Applying Life-cycle Thinking in<br />

the Framework <strong>of</strong> Cost-benefit Analysis, Banbury, Oxon: WRAP.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


536<br />

29/09/09<br />

• Second, the fact that the blue line falls slightly in the second year indicates<br />

that some garden waste – but rather less than the total collected - is<br />

diverted from residual waste collection in addition to material that may<br />

have been diverted from existing management options. However, it is<br />

arguable in this case that much <strong>of</strong> the reason for this material being<br />

disposed in the first year was due to the zero cost nature <strong>of</strong> UK residual<br />

waste collection services. This type <strong>of</strong> activity is more effectively<br />

discouraged where PBU systems are in place;<br />

• Third, and most importantly, the data for the second year shows the<br />

seasonal nature <strong>of</strong> garden waste generation. In the UK the growing season<br />

and active gardening period runs through the warm spring and summer<br />

months with generation falling nearly to zero through the winter. A similar<br />

seasonal pattern might be expected in Ireland.<br />

Figure 33-1: <strong>Waste</strong> Arisings Before and After Free Garden <strong>Waste</strong> Collection in a UK<br />

Municipality<br />

Tonnes Collected<br />

4,000<br />

3,500<br />

3,000<br />

2,500<br />

2,000<br />

1,500<br />

1,000<br />

500<br />

-<br />

Limited trial <strong>of</strong><br />

free garden waste<br />

collection service<br />

Apr-02<br />

May-02<br />

Jun-02<br />

Jul-02<br />

Aug-02<br />

Sep-02<br />

Oct-02<br />

Nov-02<br />

Dec-02<br />

Jan-03<br />

Feb-03<br />

Month<br />

Full coverage<br />

<strong>of</strong> free garden<br />

waste<br />

Mar-03<br />

Apr-03<br />

May-03<br />

Jun-03<br />

Jul-03<br />

Aug-03<br />

Sep-03<br />

Oct-03<br />

Nov-03<br />

Dec-03<br />

Jan-04<br />

All <strong>Waste</strong> Excl Kerbside Garden<br />

All <strong>Waste</strong> Incl Kerbside Garden<br />

Although food waste does not tend to exhibit observable seasonality, the variable<br />

pattern in garden waste generation has implications for the treatment systems<br />

operated. This is especially the case where food and garden waste are collected<br />

together. Seasonal garden waste generation will mean that the relative concentration<br />

<strong>of</strong> food to garden waste will vary throughout the year. This can make it difficult to<br />

optimise the treatment system and will also have a potentially negative impact on<br />

treatment economics since capacity has to be provided for peak flows, potentially<br />

giving rise to redundancy in treatment capacity. We explore this issue further in the<br />

following subsection.<br />

Experience also highlights the fact that food waste is <strong>of</strong>ten captured rather poorly by<br />

systems which focus principally on garden waste, particularly where the collection <strong>of</strong>


the organic waste fraction is no more frequent than that for residual waste.<br />

Notwithstanding these points, environmental benefits are expected to flow from the<br />

avoidance <strong>of</strong> landfilling.<br />

33.7.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

The effects in terms <strong>of</strong> waste prevention are not unequivocally positive. Experience<br />

elsewhere suggests that even where home composting schemes are promoted, if a<br />

biowaste collection is <strong>of</strong>fered to households free at the point <strong>of</strong> use, then the<br />

possibility arises whereby households will set out far more waste for collection than<br />

had hitherto been the case (see above). Once again, therefore, details <strong>of</strong><br />

implementation would need to be considered before one could pronounce on the<br />

merits or otherwise <strong>of</strong> the Circular. If there is no increase in collected quantities, for<br />

example, where charges are applied to garden waste collections, or where food waste<br />

is targeted for collection (or both), then the preventative effect could be significant.<br />

Some anecdotal evidence suggests that households who are more engaged in<br />

recycling will tend to be more sensitised to food wasting habits. 624<br />

The EU Environmental Impact <strong>of</strong> Products study suggested that the food, drink<br />

tobacco and narcotics group <strong>of</strong> products accounted for 20-30% <strong>of</strong> the environmental<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> most environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> consumption for all products (this is higher<br />

for eutrophication). The highest proportion <strong>of</strong> impacts come from meat and meat<br />

products, and from dairy products. 625 A recent review <strong>of</strong> literature also highlights<br />

potentially significant environmental impacts from food production. Other literature<br />

tends to support the view that rankings follow this pattern, though they highlight some<br />

exceptions to these rules (for example, it may be that where rice cultivation leads to<br />

methane releases from rice fields, climate change impacts are very significant). 626<br />

Significantly, WRAP estimates that for every tonne <strong>of</strong> food waste avoided, around 4.5<br />

tonnes <strong>of</strong> CO2 equ. are avoided. 627<br />

To put this into context, the greenhouse gas benefits <strong>of</strong> reducing food waste by some<br />

50kg per household (around 25% <strong>of</strong> the total) would deliver similar greenhouse gas<br />

benefits as the energy generated from combusting all <strong>of</strong> Ireland’s household waste<br />

(and would far exceed them one the emissions from the combustion itself were<br />

considered).<br />

It might be noted that the reference, in many places in the document, to ‘brown bin’<br />

collections might not necessarily be helpful. Experience in some countries suggests<br />

dedicated food waste collections might possess some features, which certainly make<br />

624 See Exodus Market Research (2008) The Food We <strong>Waste</strong>, Report for WRAP, April 2008.<br />

625 Tukker et al (2005) Environmental Impacts <strong>of</strong> Products (EIPRO) Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Life Cycle<br />

Environmental Impacts Related to the Total Final Consumption <strong>of</strong> the EU-25, IPTS/ESTO, 2005.<br />

626 See, for example, Danish Institute <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Sciences (2003) Life Cycle Assessment in the Agrifood<br />

Sector, Proceedings from the 4 th <strong>International</strong> Conference, October 6-8, 2003, Bygholm,<br />

Denmark; Manchester Business School (2006) Environmental Impacts <strong>of</strong> Food Production and<br />

Consumption, Report for Defra, December 2006.<br />

627 Personal communication with Andrew Parry, WRAP.<br />

537<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


them worthy <strong>of</strong> consideration, and that conventional ‘brown bin’ schemes, collecting<br />

both garden and food waste, might have some drawbacks. This is especially true<br />

where the issue <strong>of</strong> home composting, and maintaining activity in this respect, is<br />

concerned, and where the intention is to seek to sensitise households to the issues <strong>of</strong><br />

food wastage (although clearly other possibilities for this exist). 628<br />

33.7.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

The effects <strong>of</strong> the Circular in terms <strong>of</strong> recycling will allow Ireland to pursue its<br />

recycling rates for food and garden waste. In 2006, 64,725 tonnes <strong>of</strong> organic (food<br />

and garden) waste was recycled. This comprised 40,539 tonnes <strong>of</strong> garden and park<br />

waste, 14,806 tonnes <strong>of</strong> biodegradable kitchen and canteen waste (<strong>of</strong> which 7,888<br />

tonnes was commercial and 6,918 tonnes was household waste) and 9,381 tonnes<br />

<strong>of</strong> cooking oil. The majority <strong>of</strong> this organic waste was composted. 629 In 2007, the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> organic municipal waste recovered had increased to 78,617 tonnes, but<br />

the quantity collected from households fell in the year from 23,708 tonnes to 19,611<br />

tonnes. 630 A feature <strong>of</strong> organic collections which focus on garden waste is that their<br />

apparent success or failure is, <strong>of</strong> course, partly determined by the weather, so that<br />

year to year fluctuations are to be expected.<br />

Benefits are likely to be maximised where collection systems target food waste, and<br />

where the collected organic waste is treated through anaerobic digestion (and<br />

composting) rather than through composting alone. This latter message – regarding<br />

the superiority <strong>of</strong> anaerobic digestion from the perspective <strong>of</strong> treatment - is almost<br />

universally voiced by those who have conducted comparative assessments, including<br />

ourselves. 631 The possibilities for doing this, and the efficiency with which capital<br />

628 Eunomia (2007) Managing Biowastes from Households in the UK: Applying Life-cycle Thinking in<br />

the Framework <strong>of</strong> Cost-benefit Analysis, Banbury, Oxon: WRAP to be published in 2007.<br />

629 EPA (2008) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2006, Wexford: EPA<br />

630 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Wexford: EPA<br />

631 See, for example, Werner Edelmann and Konrad Schleiss (1999) Ecologic, Energetic and Economic<br />

Comparison <strong>of</strong> Treating Biogenic <strong>Waste</strong>s by Digesting, Composting or Incinerating, Paper written for<br />

R99, Geneva, Switzerland; Konrad Schleiss (1999) Grüngutbewirtschaftung im Kanton Zürich aus<br />

betriebswirtschlaftlicher und ökologischer Sicht: Situationsanalyse, Szenarioanalyse, ökonomische<br />

und ökologische Bewertung sowie Synthese mit MAUT, Dissertation ETH No 13,746, 1999; W.<br />

Edelmann and K. Schleiss (1999) Ökologischer, energetischer und ökonomischer Vergleich Vergärung,<br />

Kompostierung und Verbrennung fester biogener Abfallst<strong>of</strong>fe, Final report for BFE/BUWAL, BFE, CH-<br />

3003 Bern; and W. Edelmann and K. Schleiss (2002) Products, Impacts and Economy <strong>of</strong> Anaerobic<br />

Digestion <strong>of</strong> OFMSW, in in J. Mata-Alvarez (ed) (2003) Biomethanization <strong>of</strong> the Organic Fraction <strong>of</strong><br />

Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong>, London: IWA Publishing, pp. 265-301; R. Vogt, F. Knappe, J. Giegrich and A.<br />

Detzel (2002) Okobilanz Bioabfallverwertung Untershung zur Umweltvertraglichkeit von Systemen zur<br />

Verwertung von biologisch-organischen Abfallen. Initiativen zum Umweltschutz 52, Berlin; Regine Vogt,<br />

Florian Knappe and Andreas Detzel (2001) Environmental Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Systems for the Recovery <strong>of</strong><br />

Biogenic <strong>Waste</strong>, Proceedings from the ORBIT 2001 Conference; F. Knappe, R. Vogt and B. Franke<br />

(2004) Biowaste <strong>Management</strong> from an Ecological Perspective, in P. Lens, B. Hamelers, H. Hoitink and<br />

W. Bidlingmaier (2004) (eds.) Resource Recovery and Reuse in Organic Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>,<br />

London: IWA Publishing, pp. 71-9; D. Hogg et al (2002) Economic Assessment <strong>of</strong> Options for Dealing<br />

with Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong>, Report to DG Environment, European Commission, by Eunomia, Scuola<br />

Agraria del Parco di Monza, HDRA Consultants, ZREU and LDK; J-O Sundqvist et al (2002) Hur Skall<br />

538<br />

29/09/09


investments are utilised, will be influenced by the nature <strong>of</strong> the collection system.<br />

Where the system encourages a high set out <strong>of</strong> garden waste (see above) and where<br />

the material is treated through composting, then the costs <strong>of</strong> the collection and<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> additional material may outweigh benefits <strong>of</strong> the approach (although<br />

should the levy proposed for residual waste in the Main Report be adopted, it seems<br />

highly unlikely that system costs should increase – see also Annex 64.0). 632 It is<br />

important, therefore, to consider the optimisation <strong>of</strong> collection and treatment to<br />

deliver the most beneficial outcome.<br />

It is important also to re-iterate the point made above regarding the potential for food<br />

waste prevention to arise as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> separate collection.<br />

The market aspect <strong>of</strong> the output from composting and anaerobic digestion is<br />

important in securing benefits. A forthcoming report suggests that greenhouse gas<br />

benefits <strong>of</strong> compost use vary significantly according to use, being potentially as high<br />

as a net saving <strong>of</strong> 700kg/tonne <strong>of</strong> waste. The actual figure depends upon a variety <strong>of</strong><br />

factors, and poorly operated systems with limited displacement effects can indeed<br />

perform far worse (a net emission <strong>of</strong> 200kg per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste). 633<br />

The suggestion is that the benefits from use <strong>of</strong> compost / digestate may well benefit<br />

from targeted activity. Development <strong>of</strong> markets for the recovered biodegradable<br />

municipal waste is central to the success <strong>of</strong> the National Strategy on Biodegradable<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>. A Market Development Group <strong>of</strong> key stakeholders was established in 2004,<br />

under the guidance <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Department</strong>, with the objective <strong>of</strong> driving forward the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> existing markets for recyclables and identifying new applications and<br />

markets for recyclables and secondary recycled products. The recent proposal for a<br />

standard for compost is a welcomes step in this regard (see, in this context, Annex<br />

36.0). 634<br />

hushallsavfallet tas omhand – Utvardering av olika behandlingsmetoder (How Shall Municipal Solid<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> be Disposed – Assessment <strong>of</strong> Different Treatment Methods) Stockholm February 2002. IVL<br />

report B 1462; Danish EPA (2003): Skal husholdningernes madaffald brændes eller genanvendes?<br />

Samfundsøkonomisk analyse af øget genanvendelse af organisk dagrenovation (Is the food waste<br />

from the households to be incinerated or recycled? A welfare-economic analysis <strong>of</strong> increased recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> organic household waste.) Environmental project no. 814.<br />

www.mst.dk/udgiv/publikationer/2003/87-7972-685-2/html/; Nolan-ITU (2004) TBL Assessment <strong>of</strong><br />

Garden Organics <strong>Management</strong>, Final Report to the NSW Dept <strong>of</strong> Environment and Conservation,<br />

Sustainability Programs Division, May 2004; Eunomia (2007) Managing Biowastes from Households in<br />

the UK: Applying Life-cycle Thinking in the Framework <strong>of</strong> Cost-benefit Analysis, Banbury, Oxon: WRAP.<br />

632 It is always the case that the financial case for separate collection for recycling / composting /<br />

digestion are given impetus by rsing costs for dealing with residual waste. A levy such as that proposed<br />

thus supports the logic <strong>of</strong> separate collection.<br />

633 A. Boldrin, J. K. Andersen, J. Møller and T. H. Christensen (forthcoming) ’Composting and compost<br />

utilization: Accounting <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gases and global warming contribution’, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> &<br />

Research.<br />

634 See Munoo Prasad and Percy Foster (2009) Development <strong>of</strong> an Industry-led Quality Standard for<br />

Source-Separated Biodegradable Material Derived Compost (2006-WRM-DS-26), STRIVE Report No.<br />

22, Wexford: EPA.<br />

539<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


33.8 Implementation Costs<br />

The costs <strong>of</strong> implementing this Circular and its requirements are not known. Scope<br />

clearly exists in the Irish context, however, for net costs <strong>of</strong> service provision to be<br />

lower as a consequence <strong>of</strong> this measure than in a counterfactual system where<br />

biodegradable waste is landfilled. This is for the simple reason that landfill gate fees<br />

are very high, and biowaste treatment costs are likely to be lower. This suggests the<br />

potential for the measure to be <strong>of</strong> an ‘invest to save’ nature, especially if the levy<br />

proposed for residual waste in the Main Report is adopted. The issue <strong>of</strong> collection<br />

costs is examined further in Annex 64.0.<br />

The reality will depend on the details <strong>of</strong> implementation. A critical issue will be how<br />

the development <strong>of</strong> infrastructure can be made such that capacity grows in line with<br />

expected quantities <strong>of</strong> waste captured for treatment. Furthermore, the lack <strong>of</strong> any<br />

clear link between collectors and their method, and the treatment <strong>of</strong> the waste,<br />

suggests there may be some difficulties whereby treatment systems which are<br />

developed are not ideally suited to the materials being collected.<br />

33.9 Response from Public and Industry<br />

We are not aware <strong>of</strong> any document which highlights the response from public and<br />

industry. Anecdotally, it is known that some private sector operators are not well<br />

disposed to the prospect <strong>of</strong> being required to roll-out ‘brown bins’. It is interesting to<br />

note, in this respect, that whilst such operators might perceive this as an unnecessary<br />

infringement from the Irish Government, Ireland may yet have its hand forced anyway<br />

through measures highlighted in the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive. In this context, the<br />

reluctance <strong>of</strong> operators becomes less straightforward to understand.<br />

There appears to be some misunderstanding regarding the role <strong>of</strong> MBT and what it<br />

might be capable <strong>of</strong> achieving. MBT is a pre-treatment for residual waste. It is<br />

intended to complement, not replace, separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste. The outputs<br />

from MBT processes are unlikely to be <strong>of</strong> equivalent quality to those derived from<br />

source separation, and the associated benefits are likely to be considerably reduced.<br />

33.10 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The expected changes are as highlighted in the document itself, though as also<br />

hinted above, the detailed outcomes depend upon approaches to collection <strong>of</strong> waste,<br />

and choices <strong>of</strong> treatment technology. Currently, the most likely approach to collection<br />

and treatment is likely to be co-collection <strong>of</strong> food and garden waste with the material<br />

being composted. This might not deliver the best outcome for society.<br />

33.11 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

These are unclear as yet and will depend upon the detailed manner <strong>of</strong><br />

implementation. In principle, given Ireland’s relatively high landfill gate fees, if<br />

collection systems are designed efficiently, householders might pay less owing to the<br />

high avoided cost <strong>of</strong> disposal. However, much depends upon charges levied at<br />

biowaste facilities, and on the behaviour <strong>of</strong> households (and how this is incentivised).<br />

This question is intimately bound up with the design <strong>of</strong> the collection system, and the<br />

background costs <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment / disposal.<br />

540<br />

29/09/09


33.12 Complementary Policies<br />

Complementary policies are the landfill levy and its proposed expansion in scope, and<br />

the requirement to implement pay-by-use. The National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme<br />

also has a role to play, as does the proposal for a standard for composting. 635 Finally,<br />

the pace and ease with which the relevant treatment capacity can be developed will<br />

depend upon the manner <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> the Animal By-products Regulation.<br />

33.13 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

This is unclear and will be affected by the collection systems used, and the charging<br />

systems applied. The effect will also be influenced by the nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

counterfactual. With the proposed residual waste levy in place, it seems likely that the<br />

change in system costs would be negative, implying savings for households.<br />

33.14 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The arrangements for enforcement are unclear as there is no deadline as such.<br />

However, the DoEHLG would be expected to play a role through its monitoring role in<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> regional waste management plans in the short term. In addition, any<br />

revision <strong>of</strong> waste collection permits ought to reflect the Circular, though exactly how<br />

this is to be checked is unclear.<br />

33.15 Lessons Learned<br />

Probably the key lessons from the Circular thus far are that:<br />

541<br />

� The introduction <strong>of</strong> the desired collections has, understandably, not taken<br />

place ‘over night’;<br />

� There appears to be some resistance to the measure, supposedly on grounds<br />

that the approach will be expensive. It is not clear why this should necessarily<br />

affect the roll-out if the costs are recovered through charges. More<br />

fundamentally, there appears to be much for Ireland to learn with regard to<br />

optimising the design <strong>of</strong> collection services, specifically, taking advantage <strong>of</strong><br />

the possibilities for optimising logistics that biowaste collections might allow;<br />

and<br />

� Several companies appear wedded to ‘mixed waste’ biowaste treatments.<br />

Experience suggests that such approaches will tend to deliver low quality<br />

outputs which have the potential to damage the fledgling market for compost<br />

and digestion residuals. Mixed waste treatments might be more appropriately<br />

viewed as complements to, not substitutes for, separate collection <strong>of</strong><br />

biowaste. Indeed, this may yet be made a requirement in Ireland through EU<br />

635 See Munoo Prasad and Percy Foster (2009) Development <strong>of</strong> an Industry-led Quality Standard for<br />

Source-Separated Biodegradable Material Derived Compost (2006-WRM-DS-26), STRIVE Report No.<br />

22, Wexford: EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


542<br />

29/09/09<br />

legislation (so developing infrastructure on the basis that such legislation will<br />

not materialise may be an ill-fated strategy).


34.0 Minimum Recycling Standards (Household<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>) - <strong>International</strong><br />

34.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

A number <strong>of</strong> countries currently employ a minimum recycling standards policy for<br />

householders, commerce and industry, and construction and demolition wastes. This<br />

section presents those minimum standards for the household waste stream.<br />

Minimum household waste recycling policies require the separate collection <strong>of</strong> a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> waste materials either at the kerbside or via civic amenity sites, with the<br />

key goals <strong>of</strong> diverting waste away from landfill and increasing material recovery.<br />

Within the EU, the implementation <strong>of</strong> such recycling standards falls under Article 3 <strong>of</strong><br />

Directive 2006/12/EC, which specifies that Member States shall take the appropriate<br />

measures for the recovery <strong>of</strong> waste via recycling, re-use and reclamation. In Asia,<br />

countries such as Taiwan and South Korea have also implemented minimum<br />

recycling standards, driven by a lack <strong>of</strong> space in these countries and the need to<br />

move away from reliance on landfill.<br />

Within the EU, there are current proposed revisions to the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework<br />

Directive. 636 Regarding recycling, Member States will be required to take necessary<br />

measures to reach 50 % re-use and recycling <strong>of</strong> waste materials such as paper,<br />

metal, plastic and glass from households and similar waste streams by 2020. The<br />

revisions recommend that<br />

543<br />

“Member States shall set up separate collection <strong>of</strong> waste where technically,<br />

environmentally and economically practicable and appropriate to meet the<br />

necessary quality standards for the relevant recycling sectors. By 2015<br />

separate collection shall be set up for at least paper, metal, plastic and glass.”<br />

Hence the proposed revision to the framework will, in effect, require that an obligation<br />

be placed on the municipality to provide separate collections <strong>of</strong> recyclable materials.<br />

In addition to the main <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive, the use <strong>of</strong> minimum recycling<br />

standards is also designed to meet the targets stipulated in a number <strong>of</strong> more<br />

specific EU Directives, namely the Landfill Directive, the Packaging Directive (Section<br />

13.0), the Batteries and Accumulators Directive (Section 25.0), the WEEE Directive<br />

(Section 20.0) and the ELV Directive (Section 23.0).<br />

34.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

The European countries that use a minimum recycling standard for the household<br />

waste stream include Austria, Belgium (particularly Flanders and Wallonia), the Czech<br />

636 ACR+ and IBGE (2008) Focus on EU <strong>Waste</strong> Legislation, Agreement Reached on a New Framework<br />

Directive, Journal for Sustainable <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Warmer Bulletin 115, 4-5.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Republic, Denmark, England and Wales, Finland, Germany, Hungary, Italy, the<br />

Netherlands, Portugal, Slovenia, Sweden and Switzerland. In addition, both South<br />

Korea and Taiwan have also implemented minimum recycling standards in recent<br />

years, and several locations within the US also have a minimum recycling standard for<br />

their household waste, including the city <strong>of</strong> Portland, and the state <strong>of</strong> New Jersey.<br />

These minimum standards vary in the types and number <strong>of</strong> materials that must be<br />

source-separated, the way in which the materials must be collected and the way that<br />

they are funded. The main country-specific policy details are discussed in Section<br />

34.2.1.1.<br />

A minimum recycling standard has been implemented in these countries in order to<br />

push waste up the hierarchy, away from landfill, and to increase the recovery <strong>of</strong><br />

materials, so reducing the need for primary material consumption. Its implementation<br />

in Switzerland for example is considered “Environmentally sound”, with the use <strong>of</strong><br />

secondary aluminium instead <strong>of</strong> primary aluminium saving up to 95 % <strong>of</strong> the energy<br />

required to manufacture aluminium from raw materials. 637<br />

34.2.1.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

Table 34-1 summarises the key materials that must be collected separately in those<br />

countries that implement recycling mandates. A key source <strong>of</strong> information for<br />

summarising EU policies was via the European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (EIONET). 638 Additional references are provided throughout the<br />

document. The main driver behind the majority <strong>of</strong> separate collections appears to be<br />

the implementation <strong>of</strong> laws on packaging and associated producer responsibility<br />

measures, which have driven the separate collection <strong>of</strong> most materials except food<br />

and garden waste. The separate collection <strong>of</strong> food/garden waste is mainly linked to<br />

the development <strong>of</strong> compost standards, in order to create sufficient markets through<br />

standardising the products <strong>of</strong> biological treatment. Specific details for each country<br />

follow.<br />

Austria<br />

The Ordinance on the Separate Collection <strong>of</strong> Organic <strong>Waste</strong>s (Law Gazette II no.<br />

68/1992) and the Ordinance on Compost (Law Gazette II no. 292/2001) dictates<br />

that provision is made by the municipality for a separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste (food<br />

and garden waste) from Austrian households, and that the householder also has an<br />

obligation to separately collect and present their biowaste for collection. In addition,<br />

the Ordinances on Packaging (Law Gazette II No. 1996/648 and 1992/646) place<br />

responsibility on producers to ensure that a certain percentage <strong>of</strong> each type <strong>of</strong><br />

packaging material be delivered for recycling –the Altst<strong>of</strong>f Recycling Austria (ARA)<br />

green dot scheme facilitates a separate household collection <strong>of</strong> glass, plastics,<br />

637 Federal Office for the Environment (2008) Guide to <strong>Waste</strong> [Online] (Updated 28 th February 2008).<br />

Available at: http://www.bafu.admin.ch/abfall/01472/index.html?lang=en [Accessed 10 th September<br />

2008].<br />

638 European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> [Online],<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Instruments [Accessed 8th September 2008].<br />

544<br />

29/09/09


paper/cardboard, metals (aluminium and steel), and composites for beverages. The<br />

legal obligation under the Ordinance is only for packaging, but there is an agreement<br />

between ARA and the municipalities that they will also collect other types <strong>of</strong>, for<br />

example, paper and cardboard than just the packaging fraction. 639 The collections<br />

mainly consist <strong>of</strong> a comprehensive kerbside service as well as bring bank systems.<br />

Table 34-1: Materials Requiring Separate Collection According to Country<br />

Country Biowaste Glass Plastics Paper<br />

/ card<br />

545<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Aluminium Steel/<br />

tin<br />

AT � � � � � � �<br />

BE VFG and all<br />

food waste<br />

� Plastic<br />

bottles<br />

Beverage<br />

Composite<br />

s<br />

� � � � �<br />

CH � � PET � � Tin �<br />

CZ � � � �<br />

DE � � � � � tinplate �<br />

DK � �<br />

England&<br />

Wales<br />

Any two recyclables<br />

FI � � � � � �<br />

HU � � � � � �<br />

Textiles Wood<br />

IT* � � � � � � � �<br />

NL � � � �<br />

PT � � � � � �<br />

SI Garden and<br />

vegetable<br />

food waste<br />

� � � �<br />

SE � � � � � �<br />

South<br />

Korea<br />

� � � � � � � �<br />

Taiwan � � � � � � � �<br />

USA (New<br />

Jersey)<br />

� � � �<br />

*separate collection specified as requirement for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Regional Plans, with targets in<br />

place for the various materials, but does not directly state that source-separation is mandatory.<br />

Source: Table compiled from a variety <strong>of</strong> sources including the Federal Office for the Environment<br />

(2008), the European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, Fogarty et al. (2008), the<br />

Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment <strong>of</strong> the Czech Republic, ECOTEC Research and Consulting Limited (2000),<br />

Taiwan Government Information Office, and OECD (2006).<br />

639 Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry, Environment and Water <strong>Management</strong> (2006) Federal<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan 2006: Suitable for Nature and Mankind. Available at:<br />

http://www.bundesabfallwirtschaftsplan.at/


Belgium (particularly Flanders)<br />

The provision <strong>of</strong> separate collections <strong>of</strong> certain household waste streams by the<br />

municipality has been required since the 1990s. At the kerbside, separate collection<br />

<strong>of</strong> paper/cardboard, vegetable, fruit and garden waste (VFG), biowaste (including food<br />

but excluding meat), glass, plastic bottles, metal packaging, drink cartons, other<br />

metals and textiles is the responsibility <strong>of</strong> the provinces. This provision follows Article<br />

16 in Chapter 4 <strong>of</strong> the Belgian Decree concerning Prevention and <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Materials. In addition, one bring bank each for bottles and paper must also be<br />

provided for every 20,000 individuals. 640 The householder does not have a legal<br />

obligation to separately collect their waste, but is encouraged to do so by the Pay-As-<br />

You-Throw system that operates in Belgium, which charges a lower rate for<br />

separately-collected recyclables than for residual waste.<br />

Czech Republic<br />

A recent amendment to <strong>Waste</strong> Act 127/1997 in the Czech Republic now stipulates<br />

that by the end <strong>of</strong> 2010, municipalities must allow their householders to sourceseparate<br />

the following waste materials – paper/cardboard, plastics, glass, drinks<br />

cartons and biodegradable waste. 641 Packaging Act 477/2001 previously only<br />

encouraged such separation. The collections are organised by the local authority with<br />

both financial and public relations support from the Czech Republic’s producer<br />

responsibility organisation, Eko-Krom. No legal responsibility is placed on the<br />

householder to ensure that they separately collect recyclable materials. However,<br />

households and companies are incentivised to recycle, as they receive money for<br />

sorting their waste when they otherwise have to pay to dispose <strong>of</strong> their unsorted<br />

waste. 642<br />

Denmark<br />

Denmark has employed a minimum recycling policy since 1990, when it introduced<br />

the separate collection <strong>of</strong> packaging glass. In 2004, the separate collection <strong>of</strong><br />

paper/cardboard via kerbside collection schemes was also made mandatory for those<br />

municipalities with private built-up areas <strong>of</strong> greater than 1,000 inhabitants that were<br />

collecting less than 55 % <strong>of</strong> their total paper/cardboard potential in 2002. In addition,<br />

the householder in Denmark has a duty to sort their waste for separate collection. 643<br />

640 H. Fogarty, L. Reid and H. Sprott (2008) <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Recycling Policies, Scottish<br />

Government Social Research. Available at<br />

http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Resource/Doc/231872/0063356.pdf<br />

641 Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment <strong>of</strong> the Czech Republic (2008) [Online] Amendment to <strong>Waste</strong> Act- For<br />

Better Sorting and Recycling, [Accessed on 26 th September 2008], available at<br />

http://www.mzp.cz/__C12571F40024D359.nsf/$pid/mzpjkfohsria<br />

642 Resource Recovery Forum (2006) The Czech Republic – Improvement in <strong>Waste</strong> Sorting, Second in<br />

EU.<br />

643 <strong>Waste</strong> Centre Denmark (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> from Households, available at<br />

http://www.wasteinfo.dk/waste+and+collection+companies/sources+types+and+fractions/waste+fro<br />

m+households<br />

546<br />

29/09/09


England and Wales (United Kingdom)<br />

The Household <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Act (2003) states that collection authorities in<br />

England and Wales must collect at the kerbside any two recyclable materials, either<br />

together or individually separated, from the remainder <strong>of</strong> the household waste<br />

stream. In addition, Barnet Borough Council provides one example where, alongside<br />

the Household <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Act, additional responsibility for recycling is also<br />

placed on the householder. Barnet Borough Council introduced a compulsory<br />

recycling scheme in 2004, undertaking monitoring <strong>of</strong> household participation in the<br />

scheme and providing further contact and the threat <strong>of</strong> prosecution to households<br />

that failed to participate. This scheme has since been replicated in a number <strong>of</strong> other<br />

local authorities in England, and is discussed further in Section 34.4.<br />

Finland<br />

The separate collection <strong>of</strong> materials from the household waste stream is specified for<br />

paper and packaging in producer responsibility decrees 883/1998 and 962/1997<br />

respectively. The systems for collection and recovery <strong>of</strong> paper and packaging are<br />

predominantly funded via producers, but provided by municipalities. However, where<br />

the separate collection <strong>of</strong> packaging is not justified from either an environmental or<br />

economic standpoint, the municipality also becomes financially responsible for the<br />

collection and may levy charges accordingly.<br />

Germany<br />

Producer responsibility for the separate collection <strong>of</strong> all types <strong>of</strong> packaging has been<br />

in place in Germany since 1991. The ‘Green Dot Scheme’ funds and provides local<br />

collection services for glass, paper/cardboard, plastics, tinplate, aluminium and<br />

composites (see Section 14.0). In addition, the Biowaste Ordinance (1998) sets out<br />

the requirement for municipalities to provide a separate collection <strong>of</strong> food and garden<br />

waste for householders to ensure that, following composting or fermentation, only<br />

material whose content <strong>of</strong> contaminants and potentially toxic elements is negligibly<br />

low can be used as a soil improver / amendment / potting medium. Householders in<br />

Germany are not strictly obligated to use the recycling services that are provided, but<br />

are encouraged to do so due to the Pay-As-You-Throw system (see Section 9.0).<br />

Hungary<br />

The separate collection <strong>of</strong> metals, plastic, paper, glass and food/garden waste from<br />

households began in Hungary in 2001. Such collections were linked to the ban on<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong> organic waste and the environmental taxes (producer responsibility)<br />

placed on packaging. The local authority provides the collection service on behalf <strong>of</strong><br />

the producers, though the majority <strong>of</strong> collection is via bring sites in Hungary rather<br />

than a kerbside collection.<br />

Italy<br />

Decree 22/97 and more recently Decree 152/06 set out specific targets for the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> different waste streams in Italy, as well as the re-design <strong>of</strong> the packaging<br />

system towards producer responsibility. The waste streams to which targets apply,<br />

and which are thus heading towards mandatory source-separation, are<br />

paper/cardboard, glass, plastic, metal, biowaste, waste wood and textiles. In<br />

developing <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Regional Plans, Local Administrations must define<br />

547<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


local intentions regarding separate collection. The collection system in Italy is funded<br />

pre-dominantly by the municipal waste charge. 644 There is no householder obligation<br />

to recycle, but the variable portion <strong>of</strong> the Pay-As-You-Throw waste charge encourages<br />

participation in sorting schemes (see Section 8.2.2).<br />

Netherlands<br />

According to Section 10.12 <strong>of</strong> the Environment <strong>Management</strong> Act for the Netherlands,<br />

municipalities must provide householders with the ability to source-segregate their<br />

biowaste (food and garden waste), though there is no obligation on the householder<br />

to separate their waste at source. In 2001, according to the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Housing,<br />

Spatial Planning and the Environment, approximately 75 % <strong>of</strong> the population<br />

separated their biowaste. 645 In addition, separate collection <strong>of</strong> paper/cardboard,<br />

glass and textiles is specified in the provincial environmental ordinances. These<br />

requirements have been in place since 2001. 646<br />

It should be noted that there is only limited separate collection <strong>of</strong> metals in the<br />

Netherlands due to the large amount <strong>of</strong> incineration in the country, whereby a<br />

significant proportion <strong>of</strong> metals can be removed from ashes post-incineration for<br />

subsequent recycling. 646 This is linked to the ban on landfilling <strong>of</strong> household waste,<br />

which has led to incineration becoming the major means for dealing with residual<br />

waste, as well as the high tax on landfilling.<br />

Slovenia<br />

Under its Environmental Protection Act (2001), municipalities in Slovenia separately<br />

collect the following wastes from the householder: paper, plastic, metal (and<br />

packaging in general), garden waste and vegetable food waste (there is no<br />

specification for collection <strong>of</strong> Animal By Products).<br />

South Korea<br />

South Korea introduced its Volume-based <strong>Waste</strong> Fee (VBWF) in 1994. This ‘pay-byuse’<br />

based service was established in order to provide an economic incentive for<br />

waste reduction by households and also to generate revenue for the provision <strong>of</strong> a<br />

mandatory recycling service. Recyclable waste (paper, cans, bottles, metal, plastics,<br />

textiles) and food waste are all separately collected for free from the<br />

644 European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2006) Country Fact Sheet: Italy,<br />

available at http://eea.eionet.europa.eu/Public/irc/eionetcircle/etc_waste/library?l=/country_fact_sheets/italypdf/_EN_1.0_&a=d<br />

645 Ministry <strong>of</strong> Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (2001) Kitchen and Garden <strong>Waste</strong>,<br />

available at http://www.vrom.nl/Docs/internationaal/14277_174kien_garden%20was.pdf.<br />

646 ECOTEC Research and Consulting Limited (2000) Beyond the Bin: The Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Options, Report produced for Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth, UK <strong>Waste</strong> and <strong>Waste</strong> Watch. Available<br />

at http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/economics_waste_options.pdf<br />

548<br />

29/09/09


householder/small commercial sector at the point <strong>of</strong> delivery, with householders<br />

required to purchase sacks to dispose <strong>of</strong> their remaining ‘residual’ waste. 647<br />

Sweden<br />

Mandatory source separation <strong>of</strong> paper and packaging (plastic, metals, cardboard,<br />

glass, wood and beverage containers) was introduced in Sweden in 1997. Both the<br />

financial and physical responsibility for this separate collection is placed firmly on the<br />

shoulders <strong>of</strong> the producers, leaving producers to design the collection systems that<br />

they must provide, as long as they reach the national recycling targets. Hence the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> source separation in Sweden is via lower cost bring sites. In addition,<br />

Ordinance (1997:185) on Producer Responsibility for Packaging also requires the<br />

householder to separate packaging materials from other household refuse and to<br />

deliver it to the collection systems provided by the producers.<br />

Switzerland<br />

Under the Technical Ordinance on <strong>Waste</strong>, the cantons (regions) must try to recover,<br />

as far as possible, the recyclable fractions <strong>of</strong> municipal waste. Article 6 <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Ordinance <strong>of</strong> the Treatment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> prescribes the separate collection <strong>of</strong> the<br />

recyclable fraction by the cantons, and this includes kitchen waste that cannot be<br />

home composted. In addition to kitchen waste, a collection <strong>of</strong> paper/cardboard, tin,<br />

beverage containers, glass, PET and aluminium is also required, falling under the<br />

Ordinance on Beverage Containers. Household collections <strong>of</strong> these waste streams are<br />

provided by the local authority at both kerbside and via bring banks. A large part <strong>of</strong><br />

the collection system is funded by producer responsibility schemes (both statutory<br />

and voluntary). The Pay-As-You-Throw scheme that exists in the cantons provides the<br />

incentive for the householder to recycle their waste streams.<br />

Taiwan<br />

Taiwan introduced the country-wide mandatory separate collection <strong>of</strong> recyclables and<br />

food waste in 2006 as part <strong>of</strong> their ‘Zero <strong>Waste</strong> Program’. There are currently 14<br />

categories <strong>of</strong> mandatory recyclables which the municipality must collect and which<br />

the householder is obliged to separate, including steel and aluminium containers,<br />

paper, plastic, small WEEE and textiles. 648 In addition, municipalities must provide for<br />

the separate collection <strong>of</strong> food waste at the kerbside, with local government currently<br />

subsidised by the Environmental Protection Administration (EPA) for providing this<br />

service.<br />

City <strong>of</strong> Portland, Oregon (USA)<br />

The city <strong>of</strong> Portland (population approximately 575,000) in Oregon, USA, currently<br />

requires that the waste collection service providers supply weekly kerbside recycling<br />

647 S.D. Lee (2003) <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction and Recycling Law in Korea, <strong>International</strong> Environmental Law<br />

Committee - Newsletter Archive 5, February 2003, available at<br />

http://www.abanet.org/environ/committees/intenviron/newsletter/feb03/korea/<br />

648 R. Dobson (2005) Taiwan Sets Sights on Zero <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, available at<br />

http://www.bullnotbull.com/special/special-2.html.<br />

549<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


collections and fortnightly kerbside collections <strong>of</strong> garden waste for every resident,<br />

with residents encouraged to recycle due to the Pay-As-You-Throw system in place for<br />

residual waste. 649 The current required list <strong>of</strong> materials for which collection provision<br />

must be made includes cans, paper and card, glass, used motor oil and garden or<br />

‘yard’ waste.<br />

New Jersey (USA)<br />

The state <strong>of</strong> New Jersey was the first state in the USA to require that local authorities<br />

provide mandatory recycling services for all households, businesses and institutions.<br />

In 1987, the New Jersey Statewide Mandatory Source Separation and Recycling Act<br />

came into force, with householders in New Jersey also obliged to recycle leaves, and<br />

at least three <strong>of</strong> the following materials: paper, metal, glass, plastic containers and<br />

food waste.<br />

In order to help finance this Act, the tax on landfilled waste was also increased almost<br />

fourfold, yielding a State Recycling Fund intended to support the county recycling<br />

systems within New Jersey. This fund expired in 1996, and has only recently been<br />

replaced by the Recycling Enhancement Act in 2008 – re-establishing a source <strong>of</strong><br />

funding for recycling with a $3 per ton (1.02 tonnes) tax on solid waste for disposal,<br />

though such a small tax will not provide sufficient funding to fully compensate<br />

mandatory recycling schemes.<br />

34.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

For the majority <strong>of</strong> countries listed in Section 34.2.1.1, the local local local government<br />

government is<br />

charged with the implementation and management <strong>of</strong> the recycling collection system.<br />

In addition, in the majority <strong>of</strong> countries, the producer producer producer also plays a key role in the<br />

delivery <strong>of</strong> separate collection systems, because these systems are frequently linked<br />

to the requirement to recycle packaging material e.g. the Packaging Directive. The<br />

producer role is typically predominantly financial in nature, though in Sweden the<br />

producer is required to design, provide and fund all collection systems for packaging<br />

wastes. The system appears to work well when the producers and municipalities<br />

support each other – for example, in Austria, although the legal obligation under the<br />

Ordinance is only for packaging recycling, there is an agreement between the<br />

country’s green dot scheme coordinator ARA and the municipalities that ARA will also<br />

support the collection <strong>of</strong> other types <strong>of</strong>, for example, paper and cardboard than just<br />

the packaging portion.<br />

In the Netherlands, the decision was made to leave the recyclables collection function<br />

in the hands <strong>of</strong> the local government, since the municipal collection infrastructure<br />

presented the strongest opportunities to achieve recycling targets. It was also felt that<br />

having competitive industry-led collection schemes might make life more confusing<br />

for the public, thereby reducing response rates. Hence in the Netherlands, local<br />

649 Office <strong>of</strong> Sustainable Development, City <strong>of</strong> Portland (2008) Administrative Rules, Residential Solid<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> & Recycling, available at http://www.portlandonline.com/osd/index.cfm?a=217303&c=41472<br />

550<br />

29/09/09


government is responsible for the waste until the point where materials are<br />

transferred to an agreed point (e.g. depot, transfer station), following which the<br />

producers producers become responsible for the material. 650<br />

Unlike packaging materials, it should be noted however that no such producer<br />

responsibility system exists to support the collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste (food and garden<br />

waste) by those countries tasked with doing so according to their waste policies. Thus<br />

the responsibility for, and management <strong>of</strong>, the collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste in those<br />

countries which stipulate its separate collection lies with the local administration.<br />

Finally, the householder<br />

householder also plays a significant role in the implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

minimum recycling policies. Behavioural changes <strong>of</strong> the population towards their<br />

waste are fundamental in driving source-separation collection schemes. 651<br />

34.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

We have drawn on a number <strong>of</strong> evaluation studies in order to assess the impacts <strong>of</strong><br />

minimum recycling standards across a number <strong>of</strong> countries. These studies include<br />

the following:<br />

551<br />

� ECOTEC Research and Consulting Limited (2000) Beyond the Bin: The<br />

Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options, Report produced for Friends <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Earth, UK <strong>Waste</strong> and <strong>Waste</strong> Watch. Available at<br />

http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/economics_waste_options.pdf<br />

� Environmental Protection Administration (2008) Taiwan’s Zero <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> to<br />

Meet 2008 Goal in Advance, available at<br />

http://www.epa.gov.tw/en/epashow.aspx?list=112&path=11972&guid=c26a<br />

a5d0-a280-4e72-9a38-a0b4f1e2bdff&lang=en-us<br />

� Eunomia (2009) Compulsory Recycling Scheme <strong>Review</strong> and Second Phase<br />

Roll Out Plan, Final Report to the London Borough <strong>of</strong> Barnet.<br />

� Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry, Environment and Water<br />

<strong>Management</strong> (2006) Federal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan 2006: Suitable for<br />

Nature and Mankind.<br />

� H. Fogarty, L. Reid and H. Sprott (2008) <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Recycling<br />

Policies, Scottish Government Social Research. Available at<br />

http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Resource/Doc/231872/0063356.pdf<br />

� Green Alliance (2002) Creative <strong>Policy</strong> Packages for <strong>Waste</strong>: Lessons for the UK,<br />

Available at<br />

650 ECOTEC Research and Consulting Limited (2000) Beyond the Bin: The Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Options, Report produced for Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth, UK <strong>Waste</strong> and <strong>Waste</strong> Watch. Available<br />

at http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/economics_waste_options.pdf<br />

651 Federal Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety (BMU) (2006) <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> in Germany: A Driving Force for Jobs and Innovation, available at<br />

http://www.bmu.de/files/pdfs/allgemein/application/pdf/broschuere_abw_deutschland_en.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


552<br />

29/09/09<br />

http://www.greenalliance.org.uk/uploadedFiles/Publications/CPPWDenmark.<br />

pdf<br />

� D. Hogg, J. Barth, E. Favoino, M. Centemero, V. Caimi, F. Amlinger, W.<br />

Devliegher, W. Brinton and S. Antler (2002) Comparison <strong>of</strong> Compost Standards<br />

within the EU, North America and Australasia, report produced for WRAP.<br />

� Resource Recovery Forum (2006) The Czech Republic – Improvement in<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Sorting, Second in EU.<br />

� G. W. Shaumburg and K. T. Doyle (1994) Wasting Resources to Reduce <strong>Waste</strong>:<br />

Recycling in New Jersey, Cato <strong>Policy</strong> Analysis, 202.<br />

34.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The main environmental benefits from the mandatory requirement for separate<br />

collection and subsequent recycling/reuse <strong>of</strong> waste materials are likely to be:<br />

� Increased diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill or other residual waste<br />

treatments that might otherwise be required; and<br />

� The potential to re-process and consequently recycle the source-separated<br />

materials, saving on raw materials (and hence energy) in commercial and<br />

industrial processes.<br />

In most countries, it is difficult to attribute a specific increase in recycling and<br />

composting / digestion to this policy alone. This is because in most countries a policy<br />

<strong>of</strong> mandatory recycling <strong>of</strong> specific materials exists alongside other policies, including,<br />

for example, pay-by-use for households, and, as mentioned in this review, producer<br />

responsibility schemes implying provision <strong>of</strong> varying degrees <strong>of</strong> service on the part <strong>of</strong><br />

producers.<br />

To this end, the benefits <strong>of</strong> mandatory separate collection <strong>of</strong> recyclables would be<br />

assumed to be related to the benefits which studies attribute to recycling and<br />

composting / digestion more generally. For example, the Switzerland Federal<br />

Administration notes that the use <strong>of</strong> secondary aluminium instead <strong>of</strong> primary<br />

aluminium saves up to 95 % <strong>of</strong> the energy required to manufacture aluminium from<br />

raw materials. 652 In Austria, glass recycling in 2007 saved 155,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> quartz<br />

sand, 50,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> limestone and dolomite, 39,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> soda, 212 million<br />

kWh <strong>of</strong> electrical energy and 5,650,000 m 3 <strong>of</strong> gas. 653 There is also the possibility <strong>of</strong><br />

generating energy from waste (via processes such as anaerobic digestion, where both<br />

energy from biogas and a digestate product are generated).<br />

652 Federal Office for the Environment (2008) Guide to <strong>Waste</strong> [Online] (Updated 28 th February 2008).<br />

Available at: http://www.bafu.admin.ch/abfall/01472/index.html?lang=en [Accessed 10 th September<br />

2008].<br />

653 Federal Office for the Environment (2008) Guide to <strong>Waste</strong> [Online] (Updated 28 th February 2008).<br />

Available at: http://www.bafu.admin.ch/abfall/01472/index.html?lang=en [Accessed 10 th September<br />

2008].


Indeed, there are clearly synergies across these policies. For example, mandating the<br />

separate collection <strong>of</strong> a wide range <strong>of</strong> materials enhances the prospects for positive<br />

outcomes from the application <strong>of</strong> Pay-As-You-Throw (see Section 8.0). Similarly, in the<br />

context <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility schemes, the provision <strong>of</strong> services may have to be<br />

entirely funded by producers. This leaves municipalities to concentrate on the<br />

provision <strong>of</strong> biowaste collection services and refuse collection. It does not seem to be<br />

a coincidence that those countries where Pay-As-You-Throw is most widespread are<br />

also those that mandate the provision <strong>of</strong> separate collection for a wide range <strong>of</strong><br />

materials.<br />

Having said that, it seems reasonable to believe that such a policy does in fact play a<br />

role in increasing separate collection. The example <strong>of</strong> compulsory recycling in Barnet<br />

illustrates a 10 % additional increase in recycling <strong>of</strong> household materials from those<br />

households forming part <strong>of</strong> the compulsory scheme (see below). 654 Similarly, a report<br />

by Schaumburg and Doyle (1994) acknowledged that the mandatory recycling policy<br />

in New Jersey also had a direct effect on increasing recycling rates (low disposal tax<br />

ruled this out as a possible additional impact on recycling rates in this instance); for<br />

example, the recycling <strong>of</strong> glass increased from 6 % in 1980 (pre-mandate) to 31 % in<br />

1990 (post-mandate), and recycling <strong>of</strong> paper increased from 24 % in 1980 to 62 % in<br />

1990. 655 The remainder <strong>of</strong> this Section looks at examples <strong>of</strong> the potential<br />

environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> introducing mandatory recycling within individual countries.<br />

Austria<br />

Figure 34-1 illustrates the impact <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> separate collections <strong>of</strong><br />

various materials on the recycling rates in Austria. Driven by the Ordinance on the<br />

Separate Collection <strong>of</strong> Biowaste, Austria is one <strong>of</strong> the top performing countries in<br />

Europe for biowaste recycling, with a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> approximately 75-80 % <strong>of</strong> the<br />

total collectable biowaste fraction. 656 The overall municipal recycling rate (dry<br />

recyclables and biowaste) was similar to that <strong>of</strong> the Netherlands and Germany in<br />

2006 at 61 %. 657<br />

654 Eunomia (2009) Compulsory Recycling Scheme <strong>Review</strong> and Second Phase Roll Out Plan, Final<br />

Report to the London Borough <strong>of</strong> Barnet.<br />

655 G.W. Shaumburg and K.T. Doyle (1994) Wasting Resources to Reduce <strong>Waste</strong>: Recycling in New<br />

Jersey, Cato <strong>Policy</strong> Analysis, 202.<br />

656 D. Hogg, J. Barth, E. Favoino, M. Centemero, V. Caimi, F. Amlinger, W. Devliegher, W. Brinton and S.<br />

Antler (2002) Comparison <strong>of</strong> Compost Standards within the EU, North America and Australasia, report<br />

produced for WRAP.<br />

657 H. Fogarty, L. Reid H. and Sprott (2008) <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Recycling Policies, Scottish<br />

Government Social Research. Available at<br />

http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Resource/Doc/231872/0063356.pdf<br />

553<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 34-1: <strong>Waste</strong> Generation, Recovery and Disposal from Households and Similar<br />

Establishments in Austria<br />

Source: Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry, Environment and Water <strong>Management</strong> (2006)<br />

Federal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan 2006: Suitable for Nature and Mankind.<br />

Czech Republic and Germany (report by RRF) 658<br />

The 2006 RRF report highlights Germany as the European leader in the separate<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> waste materials, having sorted 60 kg <strong>of</strong> waste per capita in 2005. The<br />

well-established recycling systems in Germany produce an overall municipal recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> over 60 %. The report also highlights the Czech Republic as coming up fast<br />

through the ranks due to their recently adjusted recycling policy that stipulates the<br />

required separate collection <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> materials. The recycling rate for municipal<br />

waste in the Czech Republic leapt up 10 % between 2004 and 2005, with the<br />

separate collection <strong>of</strong> 36 kg recyclable waste per capita in 2005. Success has been<br />

attributed to the following: first, towns and companies receive money for sorting their<br />

waste when they would otherwise have to pay to dispose <strong>of</strong> their unsorted waste.<br />

Second, there has been excellent publicity to increase recycling, with endorsement<br />

from a number <strong>of</strong> famous celebrities. Third, the market for recyclable materials has<br />

658 Resource Recovery Forum (2006) The Czech Republic – Improvement in <strong>Waste</strong> Sorting, Second in<br />

EU.<br />

554<br />

29/09/09


strengthened as the increased costs <strong>of</strong> raw materials push commerce and industry to<br />

look to secondary materials. This situation may, however, be changing in the wake <strong>of</strong><br />

recent collapses in the price <strong>of</strong> some secondary materials. It remains to be seen<br />

whether this price collapse is long-lived, or a short-lived over-correction to the price <strong>of</strong><br />

these commodities.<br />

Denmark<br />

The 29 % household waste collection rate was far short <strong>of</strong> the 2000 target <strong>of</strong> 49 %.<br />

According to Green Alliance, 659 the principle reasons for this shortfall are a lack <strong>of</strong><br />

mandatory separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste and a heavy reliance on bring sites for the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> glass and paper/cardboard, as opposed to door-to-door collections.<br />

Danish waste management policy is heavily influenced by fixed investments made in<br />

the past in incineration capacity.<br />

England (Barnet Compulsory Recycling)<br />

As mentioned in Section 34.2.1.1, alongside the requirement that collection<br />

authorities in England and Wales must separately collect at the kerbside any two<br />

recyclable materials, Barnet Borough Council also implemented a compulsory<br />

recycling scheme to 25,000 households in 2004. Participation by householders<br />

involved in the scheme was monitored over a number <strong>of</strong> weeks, with those<br />

households found not to be participating subsequently sent a letter further advising<br />

them <strong>of</strong> the scheme and alerting them as to the legal basis <strong>of</strong> the scheme. Continued<br />

lack <strong>of</strong> participation resulted in further postal contact, followed by an eventual doorknocking<br />

campaign. By the end <strong>of</strong> this monitoring stage, only 9 households were still<br />

not participating.<br />

Following introduction <strong>of</strong> the compulsory scheme, the year on year increase in<br />

recycling rate for the whole <strong>of</strong> Barnet (113,000 households) rose from 10 % in 2003<br />

to more than 20 % the following year, indicating the affect <strong>of</strong> media attention on the<br />

scheme in increasing recycling across the Council, not just for the 25,000 trial<br />

households. This higher recycling rate was, however, only sustained longer-term from<br />

the 25,000 households for which recycling was compulsory, where <strong>of</strong>ficial contact<br />

from the council reinforced the message <strong>of</strong> the requirement to recycle. More than<br />

three-quarters <strong>of</strong> a survey <strong>of</strong> 500 residents in Barnet (both those on, and not on, the<br />

compulsory scheme) considered compulsory recycling to be a good idea, with support<br />

higher in those areas already forming part <strong>of</strong> the compulsory scheme, though<br />

confusion remains regarding exactly which materials form part <strong>of</strong> compulsory<br />

recycling, and even which households are part <strong>of</strong> the current scheme. 660<br />

It should be noted that the Barnet scheme incorporates the threat <strong>of</strong> legal action as a<br />

last resort in the event <strong>of</strong> non-compliance with the scheme. It remains uncertain,<br />

however, as to whether the justification which the council uses in order to stipulate<br />

659 Green Alliance (2002) Creative <strong>Policy</strong> Packages for <strong>Waste</strong>: Lessons for the UK, Available at<br />

http://www.greenalliance.org.uk/uploadedFiles/Publications/CPPWDenmark.pdf<br />

660 Eunomia (2009) Compulsory Recycling Scheme <strong>Review</strong> and Second Phase Roll Out Plan, Final<br />

Report to the London Borough <strong>of</strong> Barnet.<br />

555<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


that the specified materials are not placed into the residual waste bin (i.e. reference<br />

to sections 45 and 46 <strong>of</strong> the Environmental Protection Act 1990) would stand up in a<br />

court <strong>of</strong> law. A similar case in Exeter in 2006 saw the council lose against a<br />

householder, as the council was not able to prove, beyond all reasonable doubt, that<br />

it was indeed that individual who had put the <strong>of</strong>fending material in the bin. 661<br />

Hungary<br />

According to EIONET 662, the introduction <strong>of</strong> separate collections for a number <strong>of</strong><br />

waste streams (predominantly at bring sites) has led to a change in the attitude <strong>of</strong> the<br />

population towards their waste and the engagement <strong>of</strong> the private sector into the<br />

separate collection process. So far, separate collection has led to the recovery <strong>of</strong><br />

approximately 10 % <strong>of</strong> the generated municipal solid waste.<br />

The Netherlands<br />

According to ECOTEC, 663 research was undertaken in the Netherlands between 1993<br />

and 1995 to see whether a national, broadly uniform, separate collection system<br />

could be undertaken for the dry recycling components <strong>of</strong> household waste. The<br />

system that was developed consisted <strong>of</strong> the collection <strong>of</strong> glass at bring banks (1 per<br />

every 650 inhabitants), kerbside collection for paper and board at least once a month<br />

and textiles collection at least once a quarter (plus in bring banks). Discussions<br />

around the model led to the decision to leave the collection function to the<br />

government in the Netherlands, with the municipal collection infrastructure <strong>of</strong>fering<br />

the best opportunities for reaching recycling targets. Collection <strong>of</strong> plastics at the<br />

kerbside was also studied, but was found to be uneconomic. 664 Several additional<br />

enhancements to the service were proposed, such as the use <strong>of</strong> can banks, plastic<br />

bottle banks and drinks cartons collections. The relatively simple model gave a strong<br />

guideline for local authorities to follow. As a result, even as far back as 1996 the<br />

Netherlands was achieving separate collection rates for recycling/reuse <strong>of</strong> 44 %. In<br />

2006, this rate had increased to 64 %. 665<br />

South Korea<br />

As a consequence <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> the Volume-based <strong>Waste</strong> Fee (VBWF)<br />

combined with a mandatory recycling service, the recycling rate in South Korea rose<br />

661 LetsRecycle.com (2006) Exeter Loses Court Case over Recycling Contamination.<br />

662 European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> [Online],<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Instruments [Accessed 8th September 2008].<br />

663 ECOTEC Research and Consulting Limited (2000) Beyond the Bin: The Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Options, Report produced for Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth, UK <strong>Waste</strong> and <strong>Waste</strong> Watch. Available<br />

at http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/economics_waste_options.pdf<br />

664 Resource Recovery Forum (2004) High Diversion <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>: Is It Achievable?<br />

665 H. Fogarty, L. Reid and H. Sprott (2008) <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Recycling Policies, Scottish<br />

Government Social Research. Available at<br />

http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Resource/Doc/231872/0063356.pdf<br />

556<br />

29/09/09


from 15.4 % in 1994 to 49.2 % in 2004. 666<br />

Switzerland<br />

Statistics provided on the Federal Office for the Environment (FOEN) 667 website<br />

indicate that the municipal waste recycling rate in Switzerland has been over 40 % for<br />

a number <strong>of</strong> years, with capture rates in 2006 for individual materials as follows:<br />

paper at 77 %, aluminium cans at 90 %, PET bottles at 76 %, biowaste at 34 % and<br />

glass particularly high at 95.6 %.<br />

Taiwan<br />

The original recycling target linked to the introduction <strong>of</strong> mandatory recycling in 2006<br />

was to reach 28.75 % by 2008; Taiwan had already exceeded this rate by 2007 with<br />

a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 38.7%. 668<br />

New Jersey (USA)<br />

The total municipal (including businesses and institutions) recycling rate in New<br />

Jersey in 2006 was reported as 54.8 %. 669 A report by Schaumburg and Doyle (1994)<br />

condemned the mandatory recycling scheme in New Jersey due to the high cost <strong>of</strong><br />

administering and running such a system, whilst acknowledging that the policy has<br />

had a direct effect on increasing recycling rates. 670<br />

34.6 Implementation Costs<br />

In countries such as Austria, the Czech Republic, Germany and Switzerland, the<br />

minimum recycling standards for packaging materials are principally funded by<br />

producer responsibility schemes (which are in turn supported by pre-paid disposal<br />

fees). This means that in, for example, Switzerland, the producer fully funds<br />

aluminium collection, mostly funds glass collection and partly funds paper/cardboard<br />

collection. Such schemes are discussed in more detail in Section 13.0.<br />

By contrast, countries such as the UK and Denmark pay for their recycling collection<br />

schemes predominantly via local taxes. In Denmark, in some situations, pay-by-use is<br />

also used in some municipalities in order to promote source separation <strong>of</strong> waste (see<br />

Section 8.0). In the UK, in the past, the costs <strong>of</strong> implementation and running <strong>of</strong> door-<br />

666 OECD (2006) Impacts <strong>of</strong> Unit-Based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges, Working Group on <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

and Recycling, Environment <strong>Policy</strong> Committee.<br />

667 Available at http://www.bafu.admin.ch/abfall/01517/01519/index.html?lang=en<br />

668 Environmental Protection Administration (2008) Taiwan’s Zero <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> to Meet 2008 Goal in<br />

Advance, available at<br />

http://www.epa.gov.tw/en/epashow.aspx?list=112&path=11972&guid=c26aa5d0-a280-4e72-9a38a0b4f1e2bdff&lang=en-us<br />

669 New Jersey <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environmental Protection (2006) New Jersey Generation, Disposal and<br />

Recycling Statistics, available online at<br />

http://www.state.nj.us/dep/dshw/recycling/stat_links/06%20Disposal_%20Rates_%20County.pdf.<br />

670 G.W. Shaumburg and K.T. Doyle (1994) Wasting Resources to Reduce <strong>Waste</strong>: Recycling in New<br />

Jersey, Cato <strong>Policy</strong> Analysis, 202.<br />

557<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


to-door source-separation schemes have tended to be higher than collection based<br />

around refuse collection for disposal only. This has been because the cost <strong>of</strong> disposal<br />

has been so low. However, past increases in landfill tax are already making separate<br />

collection more economically favourable longer-term, this already being the case for<br />

many materials such as paper and card, and where refuse frequency is reduced at<br />

the same time, for food waste also. 671 The financial rationale for recycling is likely to<br />

strengthen as landfill taxes are set to increase in future years.<br />

The Netherlands provides an example <strong>of</strong> increasing costs resulting from minimum<br />

recycling standards. Its system <strong>of</strong> municipality responsibility from collection until the<br />

transfer station, followed by the shift <strong>of</strong> responsibility to the producer incurred a per<br />

capita waste levy increase. The levy more than doubled between 1991 and 1997,<br />

standing at 377 guilders (£122) in 2000. 672 However, it should be stated that this<br />

was a period during which the cost <strong>of</strong> disposal also increased as a consequence <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill taxes and bans, so the increase in costs could not be attributed to the<br />

changes in the collection system alone.<br />

It should be noted that no such producer responsibility systems exist to support the<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste by those countries tasked with doing so according to their<br />

waste policies. Nonetheless, costs for the collection <strong>of</strong> biowastes need not be<br />

enormous: a large amount <strong>of</strong> any additional cost has been linked to the tendency to<br />

pull out <strong>of</strong> the waste stream materials which might otherwise not have been collected<br />

at all (e.g. garden waste) or would otherwise have been delivered to bring sites. As a<br />

result, countries with biowaste collections, notably Belgium, Austria and Germany,<br />

strongly promote home composting alongside the biowaste collection and Italy and<br />

parts <strong>of</strong> Catalunya have designed collection systems to specifically target kitchen<br />

waste only. 673 A detailed modelling study undertaken by Eunomia on food waste<br />

collection systems in the United Kingdom found that collection operations were more<br />

or less cost-neutral where residual waste collection frequencies were reduced at the<br />

same time. Recent shifts in the cost <strong>of</strong> treatment and disposal <strong>of</strong> waste are making<br />

the separate collection <strong>of</strong> food waste increasingly cost effective. 674 Likewise, at higher<br />

disposal costs and/ or higher participation rates, recycling schemes overall will begin<br />

to pay for themselves (particularly once reaching a 12.5 % diversion rate), though the<br />

degree to which this will be the case will rely on the market price <strong>of</strong> the recyclable<br />

671 Eunomia (2008) Mid Devon District Council Kerbside Collection Report, Report produced for WRAP;<br />

Eunomia (2007) WRAP REP.<br />

672 ECOTEC Research and Consulting Limited (2000) Beyond the Bin: The Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Options, Report produced for Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth, UK <strong>Waste</strong> and <strong>Waste</strong> Watch. Available<br />

at http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/economics_waste_options.pdf<br />

673 Eunomia (2001) Costs for Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in the EU, Final Report to Directorate<br />

General Government, European Commission.<br />

674 Eunomia (2008) Food <strong>Waste</strong> Collection: Update to WRAP Cost Benefit Study, Report produced for<br />

WRAP.<br />

558<br />

29/09/09


materials. 675 Thus complementary policies have a key role to play in determining the<br />

implementation costs <strong>of</strong> such a service.<br />

Cost-Benefit Analysis <strong>of</strong> separate collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> waste materials in New<br />

Zealand<br />

A recent study (2007) delivered by Covec on behalf <strong>of</strong> the Ministry for the<br />

Environment in New Zealand 676 examined the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling paper,<br />

plastics, glass, organics (food and garden waste), C&D waste, tyres and used oil. The<br />

study compared the cost <strong>of</strong> disposal to landfill to the delivery <strong>of</strong> a kerbside collection<br />

and subsequent recycling <strong>of</strong> the materials. The costs <strong>of</strong> recycling include the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

collection and sorting minus the value <strong>of</strong> the materials in the end-user markets.<br />

Analysis for each material used three sets <strong>of</strong> assumptions:<br />

559<br />

� An initial recycling rate based on benefit estimates that include savings in<br />

landfill costs but ignore external costs associated with emissions, leachate<br />

and direct consumer benefits;<br />

� A low benefit estimate where the savings were assigned low values per tonne<br />

and included external costs; and<br />

� A high benefit estimate where the savings were assigned higher values per<br />

tonne and also included external costs.<br />

Analysis showed that there is the potential to increase recycling rates at a positive<br />

net-benefit for all waste streams using the high-benefit estimates. However, when<br />

lower values were assigned for the savings, separate collections <strong>of</strong> PVC, LDPE and<br />

organics (combined food and garden waste) showed a negative net-benefit. For the<br />

organic material, this cost was particularly associated with a shift in garden waste<br />

tonnage from civic amenity sites to the co-mingled collections at the kerbside.<br />

34.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

As with environmental benefits, it is difficult to trace technical changes and<br />

innovations to one specific policy. However, the push to increase recycling is likely to<br />

have had the effect <strong>of</strong> encouraging collectors/reprocessors to ensure that the<br />

material which they are collecting/delivering to the market is high-quality.<br />

Key areas <strong>of</strong> technical change/ innovation associated with the implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

minimum recycling standards are the development <strong>of</strong> vehicles in order to collect<br />

separated waste efficiently from households, the development <strong>of</strong> markets for the<br />

recyclable materials and the development <strong>of</strong> biowaste treatment infrastructure. The<br />

increasing collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste has seen an increase in the development <strong>of</strong> both<br />

675 ECOTEC Research and Consulting Limited (2000) Beyond the Bin: The Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Options, Report produced for Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth, UK <strong>Waste</strong> and <strong>Waste</strong> Watch. Available<br />

at http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/economics_waste_options.pdf<br />

676 Covec (2007) Recycling: Cost Benefit Analysis, prepared for the Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment, New<br />

Zealand.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


composting and anaerobic digestion facilities in countries such as Germany and<br />

Austria.<br />

34.8 Complementary Policies<br />

Key complementary policies applied in conjunction with minimum recycling standards<br />

are as follows:<br />

560<br />

� Financial support to the collection systems:<br />

29/09/09<br />

• Producer responsibility; particularly that associated with packaging<br />

decrees;<br />

• Deposit refund schemes;<br />

• Pay as you throw (where residual waste collection cost exceeds that <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling and biowaste collections to encourage householders to<br />

separate and recycle their waste).<br />

� <strong>Policy</strong> measures that discourage disposal:<br />

• Landfill tax - increases in tax support the increasing cost-effectiveness<br />

<strong>of</strong> collection systems;<br />

• Landfill bans – for example the ban <strong>of</strong> biowaste means that such waste<br />

must be separated from the remaining waste for disposal via other<br />

methods or that the waste must be pre-treated before going to landfill;<br />

• Pay as you throw (where residual waste collection cost exceeds that <strong>of</strong><br />

recycling and biowaste collections to encourage householders to<br />

separate and recycle their waste).<br />

� Product standards e.g. compost standards for use in agriculture require that<br />

the biowaste is source-segregated (in Austria and many other countries) 677 ;<br />

and<br />

� Recycled content requirements, e.g. the Green Public Procurement policy in<br />

Italy requires that a minimum <strong>of</strong> 30 % <strong>of</strong> the goods/products purchased by<br />

local government must be made from recycled materials, thus helping to<br />

develop an end-user market. 678<br />

In addition to the above, targets for recycling, or for the amount <strong>of</strong> residual waste<br />

collected, tend to reinforce the requirement to separately collect materials.<br />

677 D. Hogg, J. Barth, E. Favoino, M. Centemero, V. Caimi, F. Amlinger, W. Devliegher, W. Brinton and S.<br />

Antler (2002) Comparison <strong>of</strong> Compost Standards within the EU, North America and Australasia, report<br />

produced for WRAP.<br />

678 European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> [Online],<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Instruments [Accessed 8th September 2008].


34.9 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

Residual waste treatment and disposal typically have associated with them external<br />

costs. Collection <strong>of</strong> residual waste is typically relatively cheap. Recycling, on the other<br />

hand, can incur higher collection costs, even though the avoided costs <strong>of</strong> treatment /<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> residual waste may justify the activity from the perspective <strong>of</strong> overall<br />

system costs. Recycling typically implies positive externalities relative to the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> material from primary resources. 679 However, governments rarely<br />

provide subsidies for recycling.<br />

In the absence <strong>of</strong> a high landfill tax and <strong>of</strong> direct pay-by-use (which would directly<br />

deliver the economic stimulus to better manage resources), mandatory recycling can<br />

imply some extra costs for the consumer to fund recycling schemes. Although the<br />

policy does not directly align the costs <strong>of</strong> purchasing goods with the environmental<br />

damage costs, it can force the ‘polluter to pay’ to have their waste recycled.<br />

Contributions made by producer responsibility schemes, and the degree to which they<br />

cover the costs <strong>of</strong> the collection scheme in each individual country will also impact<br />

the overall cost <strong>of</strong> the provision <strong>of</strong> mandatory recycling schemes.<br />

34.10 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

In Switzerland the current producer responsibility schemes that facilitate the majority<br />

<strong>of</strong> recycling are working well. However, if retailers should start to jeopardise the<br />

financing <strong>of</strong> collection via free-riding, the government proposes to introduce a<br />

mandatory charge, as is provided for in the Environmental Protection Law. 680<br />

34.11 Lessons Learned<br />

Denmark<br />

As previously discussed, the 29 % household waste collection rate fell far short <strong>of</strong> the<br />

2000 target <strong>of</strong> 49 % in Denmark despite the minimum recycling standards. According<br />

to Green Alliance, 681 the principle reasons for this shortfall are a lack <strong>of</strong> mandatory<br />

separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste and a heavy reliance on bring sites for the collection<br />

<strong>of</strong> glass and paper/cardboard, leading to poor capture rates.<br />

When the government subsequently proposed the kerbside collection <strong>of</strong> paper, the<br />

public voted against it due to the perceived increase in expense to the<br />

679 See, for example, ECOTEC Research and Consulting Limited (2000) Beyond the Bin: The Economics<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options, Report produced for Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth, UK <strong>Waste</strong> and <strong>Waste</strong> Watch.<br />

Available at http://www.foe.co.uk/resource/reports/economics_waste_options.pdf; D. Hogg (2006)<br />

Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges, Report for the OECD Environment Directorate, Working<br />

Group on <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and recycling, May 2006.<br />

680 Federal Office for the Environment (2008) Guide to <strong>Waste</strong> [Online] (Updated 28 th February 2008).<br />

Available at: http://www.bafu.admin.ch/abfall/01472/index.html?lang=en [Accessed 10 th September<br />

2008].<br />

681 Green Alliance (2002) Creative <strong>Policy</strong> Packages for <strong>Waste</strong>: Lessons for the UK, Available at<br />

http://www.greenalliance.org.uk/uploadedFiles/Publications/CPPWDenmark.pdf<br />

561<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


householder. 682 According to Lone Lykke Nielson “Systems are needed but many<br />

municipalities are reluctant to act and the collection <strong>of</strong> organic household waste has<br />

not been made mandatory”. Only four per cent <strong>of</strong> organic domestic waste is being<br />

recovered in biogas plants. Henrik Wejdling also pointed out that Denmark already<br />

has incineration plants to feed and is reluctant to put much money into alternatives,<br />

whilst the disposal cost is too low to incentivise further source-separation. 682<br />

For similar reasons, Denmark was a fairly vociferous opponent <strong>of</strong> proposals at the EU<br />

level to introduce a Biowaste Directive that would mandate biowaste collection in all<br />

municipalities. Part <strong>of</strong> the reason was that, recognizing that the marginal benefit <strong>of</strong><br />

avoided disposal would be close to zero because such a move would simply free up<br />

incineration capacity, there would be little cost saving on the disposal side.<br />

The lesson appears to be that where minimum standards are set, they should be<br />

sufficiently specific in terms <strong>of</strong> the quality <strong>of</strong> service they envisage. In addition, the<br />

Danish experience suggests that countries that have already invested heavily in<br />

residual waste treatment infrastructure are less likely to look favourably upon such<br />

standards precisely because <strong>of</strong> the sunk costs in existing infrastructure.<br />

United Kingdom (England and Wales)<br />

It should be noted that the recycling targets that typically complement minimum<br />

recycling standards can have negative as well as positive impacts. The collection<br />

authorities in England and Wales must collect at the kerbside any two recyclable<br />

materials, with minimum recycling targets also set without reference to specific<br />

material types. Thus, local authorities habitually pursue the collection <strong>of</strong> garden<br />

waste, which typically increases the overall amount <strong>of</strong> this waste ending up in the<br />

waste system (where it might previously have been home-composted or left in-situ),<br />

proving costly to the authority in question. 683<br />

34.12 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

As stated in the Federal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan, 684 Austria recommends the<br />

following for the separate collection <strong>of</strong> waste materials:<br />

� Requirement for strong promotion and motivational campaigns to get the<br />

public involved and participating in effective source-separation (i.e. high<br />

recognition rates);<br />

� The periodic analysis <strong>of</strong> the residual waste composition in order to improve the<br />

separate collection <strong>of</strong> waste materials – with particular focus on problematic<br />

materials;<br />

682 H. Fogarty, L. Reid and H. Sprott (2008) <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Recycling Policies, Scottish<br />

Government Social Research. Available at<br />

http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Resource/Doc/231872/0063356.pdf<br />

683 WRAP/Eunomia (2008) Food <strong>Waste</strong> Collection: Update to WRAP Biowaste Cost Benefit Study,<br />

October 2008.<br />

684 Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry, Environment and Water <strong>Management</strong> (2006) Federal<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan 2006: Suitable for Nature and Mankind. Available at:<br />

http://www.bundesabfallwirtschaftsplan.at/<br />

562<br />

29/09/09


� Strong industrial support via producer responsibility schemes; and<br />

� Careful specification <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment capacity so as not to<br />

undermine potential future recycling initiatives.<br />

It is also useful to understand the relative costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> mandating the<br />

collection/treatment <strong>of</strong> specific waste streams.<br />

563<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


35.0 Minimum Recycling Standards<br />

(Commercial and Industrial <strong>Waste</strong>) - <strong>International</strong><br />

35.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

A number <strong>of</strong> countries currently employ a minimum recycling standards policy for<br />

householders, commerce and industry, and construction and demolition wastes. This<br />

section presents those minimum standards for the commercial and industrial (C&I)<br />

waste stream. Minimum recycling policies require the separate collection <strong>of</strong> a number<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste materials, with the key goals <strong>of</strong> diverting waste away from landfill and<br />

increasing material recovery.<br />

Within the EU, the implementation <strong>of</strong> such recycling standards comes under Article 3<br />

<strong>of</strong> Directive 2006/12/EC, which specifies that Member States shall take the<br />

appropriate measures for the recovery <strong>of</strong> waste via recycling, re-use and reclamation.<br />

Outside <strong>of</strong> the EU, several places within the US have also implemented or are<br />

currently moving towards mandatory C&I recycling (see Section 35.2.1).<br />

In addition to the main EU <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive, the use <strong>of</strong> minimum recycling<br />

standards in Europe is also designed to meet the targets stipulated in a number <strong>of</strong><br />

more specific EU Directives, namely the Landfill Directive, the Packaging Directive<br />

(Section 13.0), the Batteries and Accumulators Directive (Section 25.0), the WEEE<br />

Directive (Section 20.0) and the ELV Directive (Section 23.0).<br />

35.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

The countries that currently use a minimum recycling standard for the C&I sector<br />

include Austria, Denmark, Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal,<br />

Slovenia and Switzerland. In addition, the city <strong>of</strong> Portland and the state <strong>of</strong> New Jersey<br />

also require a minimum recycling standard from their businesses. California (USA) is<br />

also looking to implement a mandatory commercial recycling programme. The<br />

minimum standards for C&I vary in the types and number <strong>of</strong> materials that must be<br />

source-separated, the way in which the materials must be collected and in the way<br />

that they are funded. The main country-specific policy details are discussed in Section<br />

35.2.1.<br />

A minimum recycling standard for C&I has been implemented in these countries in<br />

order to push waste up the hierarchy away from landfill, and to increase the recovery<br />

<strong>of</strong> materials and hence reduce the need for primary material consumption.<br />

35.2.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

Austria<br />

The Ordinance on the Separate Collection <strong>of</strong> Organic <strong>Waste</strong>s (Law Gazette II no.<br />

68/1992) and the Ordinance on Compost (Law Gazette II no. 292/2001) dictate that<br />

provision is made by the municipality for a separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste from<br />

Austrian commercial and industrial properties (that fall under the remit <strong>of</strong> the<br />

564<br />

29/09/09


municipality) unless it is composted/treated onsite. In addition, these Ordinances<br />

stipulate that C&I operators are obliged to separate, where applicable, plant residues<br />

from C&I processing and from the distribution <strong>of</strong> agricultural and forestry products,<br />

and vegetable food waste from commercial enterprises. In addition, the Ordinances<br />

on Packaging (Law Gazette II No. 1996/648 and 1992/646) place financial<br />

responsibility on producers to ensure that the separate collection <strong>of</strong> glass, plastics,<br />

paper/cardboard, metals (aluminium and steel) and composites for beverages occurs<br />

from C&I as well as households.<br />

Denmark<br />

Municipalities have an obligation to provide a collection service for the following C&I<br />

waste streams: food waste from catering centres, paper/cardboard from commercial<br />

properties and transport packaging waste. In turn, C&I operators in Denmark have a<br />

responsibility to ensure that they separate out their food, paper, cardboard, and<br />

plastic transport packaging waste streams where applicable. There are also some<br />

specific-industry examples where certain additional streams must be sourceseparated<br />

such as steel drums and impregnated wood.<br />

Finland<br />

Paper must be separately collected by C&I waste producers. In Helsinki, any premises<br />

comprising more than four dwellings and any major C&I generators <strong>of</strong> paper and<br />

cardboard are provided with a collection service by the municipality. 685<br />

Germany<br />

The separate collection <strong>of</strong> glass, paper/cardboard, plastics, tinplate, aluminium and<br />

composites has been required from C&I waste in Germany since 2002. In addition,<br />

the Biowaste Ordinance (1998) sets out the requirement for the separate collection<br />

<strong>of</strong> biowaste from C&I waste where applicable, to ensure that only biodegradable<br />

waste with a low pollutant content is used in fertiliser following composting or<br />

fermentation. Companies are obliged to either separate their own waste and have it<br />

collected, or commit their waste to special commercial waste sorting facilities.<br />

The Netherlands<br />

The Separate Collection <strong>of</strong> Commercial/Industrial <strong>Waste</strong> Programme sets out that<br />

paper, cardboard and packaging must be separated by C&I waste producers for<br />

recycling in the Netherlands. Companies must arrange for these waste streams to be<br />

separately collected. In addition, glass, plastic, organics, wood, textiles and metals<br />

must also be collected where it is ‘reasonably practicable’ to do so. The obligation to<br />

separate is currently specified in the C&I Environmental Licence, though this Licence<br />

685 J. Saarela (2004) <strong>Waste</strong>s In Finland and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Strategies in Helsinki Metropolitan<br />

Area, available at http://www.ymparisto.fi/download.asp?contentid=80498<br />

565<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


is being replaced by more general rules relating to particular C&I sectors, following<br />

Section 8.40 <strong>of</strong> the Environmental <strong>Management</strong> Act. 686<br />

Poland<br />

Packaging must be separately collected from retailer shops with a trading area<br />

greater than 2,000 m 2. Retailers must organise their own collections.<br />

Slovenia<br />

Under the Environmental Protection Act (2001), C&I that produce both garden waste<br />

and vegetable food waste must ensure that this waste stream is separately collected.<br />

Switzerland<br />

Under the Technical Ordinance on <strong>Waste</strong>, the cantons (regions) must try to recover,<br />

as far as possible, the recyclable fractions <strong>of</strong> municipal waste (including SME as well<br />

as larger C&I wastes that come under the jurisdiction <strong>of</strong> the canton). Article 6 <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Ordinance <strong>of</strong> the Treatment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> prescribes the separate collection <strong>of</strong> the<br />

recyclable fraction, and includes biowaste that cannot be home composted. In<br />

addition to biowaste, a collection <strong>of</strong> paper/cardboard, tin, beverage containers, glass,<br />

PET and aluminium is also required, falling under the Ordinance on Beverage<br />

Containers. C&I waste producers are obliged to ensure the separate collection <strong>of</strong><br />

these waste streams where the authority considers it technically and economically<br />

viable to do so, and must arrange for the collection <strong>of</strong> these waste streams either via<br />

the local authority, or via private collections for larger C&I, which are facilitated by prepaid<br />

disposal fees.<br />

California (USA)<br />

The California Air Resources Board (ARB) voted to apply a mandatory commercial<br />

recycling programme as part <strong>of</strong> the ‘AB 32 Scoping Plan’, which is the blueprint for<br />

implementing California’s global warming legislation. The state has identified<br />

recycling as one <strong>of</strong> the key strategies in helping California to achieve its targets in<br />

reducing greenhouse gas emissions going forward. In addition, the Scoping Plan also<br />

recognises that the provision <strong>of</strong> financial incentives will be critical to the success <strong>of</strong><br />

the recycling programme; the ARB will work with, among others, the California<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Food and Agriculture and the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Transportation, to provide<br />

direct incentives for the use <strong>of</strong> compost in agriculture and landscaping. Furthermore,<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> incentives in order to encourage the collection <strong>of</strong> both household and<br />

commercial food waste for both composting and anaerobic digestion processes will<br />

also be explored by the California Integrated <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board. 687<br />

686 Ministry <strong>of</strong> Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (2001) Commercial/Industrial <strong>Waste</strong><br />

and Compulsory Separation, available at<br />

http://www.sharedspaces.nl/docs/internationaal/14274_174com_indwaste.pdf.<br />

687 S. Smithline (2008) Recycling to Play Critical Role in State's Landmark Global Warming Plan,<br />

Available at http://www.cawrecycles.org/node/3200, [Accessed on 2 nd January 2009].<br />

566<br />

29/09/09


City <strong>of</strong> Portland, Oregon (USA)<br />

The city <strong>of</strong> Portland in Oregon, USA, currently requires that all businesses separate<br />

out a minimum <strong>of</strong> 75 % <strong>of</strong> their waste for recycling. Those failing to do so are required<br />

to demonstrate why they are unable to meet this requirement. All paper and<br />

cardboard is to be recycled, and organic material is to be recycled where the Office <strong>of</strong><br />

Sustainable Development determines that the amount produced is sufficient to<br />

warrant separate collection. Where glass forms part <strong>of</strong> the recyclable materials, this<br />

should be collected separately from any other materials. This measure is intended to<br />

maintain the quality <strong>of</strong> the collected paper and card. Free government assistance, in<br />

the form <strong>of</strong> a ‘’Recycle at Work’’ programme, is also provided to help businesses<br />

achieve this rate. 688<br />

The regional government in Portland area, known as Metro, is looking to expand this<br />

current policy to the wider Portland region (population approximately 2 million), and<br />

also to increase the recycling rate required to 90 % for paper, cardboard and<br />

containers. Metro analysts have estimated that this mandate would boost recycling by<br />

55,000 tons a year, particularly for paper. The wider mandate would allow the<br />

government to inspect the estimated 14 % <strong>of</strong> businesses that currently do little or no<br />

recycling.<br />

New Jersey (USA)<br />

The state <strong>of</strong> New Jersey was the first state in the USA to require mandatory recycling<br />

from all households, businesses and institutions. In 1987, the New Jersey Statewide<br />

Mandatory Source Separation and Recycling Act came into force, with all households<br />

required to recycle leaves and at least three <strong>of</strong> the following materials: paper, metal,<br />

glass, plastic containers and food waste. In addition to these materials, the<br />

commercial sector is also required to recycle its <strong>of</strong>fice paper and corrugated<br />

cardboard waste.<br />

35.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

C&I separate collections are typically funded by the businesses themselves in the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> countries listed in Section 35.2. The collection systems are predominantly<br />

privately co-ordinated and funded in Austria, Finland, Germany, Poland, Switzerland<br />

and the USA. Local government provides the collection service itself for C&I waste<br />

recycling in Denmark, Slovenia, for biowaste collections in Austria, and for SMEs<br />

under the jurisdiction <strong>of</strong> the municipality in Switzerland.<br />

35.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

Federal Office for the Environment, 2008, Guide to <strong>Waste</strong> [Online] (Updated 28 th<br />

February 2008). Available at:<br />

688 Office <strong>of</strong> Sustainable Development, City <strong>of</strong> Portland (2008) Fall 2008 Revisions, Administrative<br />

Rules, Commercial Solid <strong>Waste</strong>, Recycling and Compostables, available at<br />

http://www.portlandonline.com/osd/index.cfm?c=41472&a=218220<br />

567<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


http://www.bafu.admin.ch/abfall/01472/index.html?lang=en [Accessed 10 th<br />

September 2008].<br />

Shaumburg, G. W. and Doyle, K. T. (1994) Wasting Resources to Reduce <strong>Waste</strong>:<br />

Recycling in New Jersey, Cato <strong>Policy</strong> Analysis, 202.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Centre Denmark, [Online], <strong>Waste</strong> from Industry and Commerce. Available at<br />

http://www.wasteinfo.dk/waste+and+collection+companies/sources+types+and+fra<br />

ctions/waste+from+industry+and+commerce [Accessed 29 th September 2008].<br />

35.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The main environmental benefits from the mandatory requirement for separate<br />

collection and subsequent recycling/reuse <strong>of</strong> waste materials are likely to be:<br />

568<br />

� Increased diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill or other residual waste<br />

treatments that might otherwise be required; and<br />

� The potential to re-process and consequently recycle the source-separated<br />

materials, saving on raw materials (and hence energy) in commercial and<br />

industrial processes.<br />

In most countries, it is difficult to attribute a specific increase in recycling and<br />

composting / digestion to this policy alone. This is because in most countries a policy<br />

<strong>of</strong> mandatory recycling <strong>of</strong> specific materials exists alongside other policies, including,<br />

for example, producer responsibility schemes, implying provision <strong>of</strong> varying degrees <strong>of</strong><br />

service on the part <strong>of</strong> producers. Having said that, it seems reasonable to believe that<br />

such a policy does in fact play a role in increasing materials recycling. For example,<br />

approximately one third <strong>of</strong> the total biowaste collected in Switzerland is from private<br />

industry (notably horticulture and landscaping). 689 Similarly, the total municipal<br />

(including businesses and institutions) recycling rate in New Jersey in 2006 was<br />

reported as 54.8 %, reaching the target set by the state for its municipal solid waste<br />

stream. 690<br />

Not much information appears to exist on the specific contribution <strong>of</strong> C&I to overall<br />

recycling rates in the countries listed. In Denmark, for example, only certain industries<br />

must keep a register or their waste generation. Thus it is difficult to obtain a complete<br />

picture <strong>of</strong> increases in recycling rates due to mandatory separation requirements.<br />

However, from the <strong>Waste</strong> Statistics available in Denmark, approximately 65 % <strong>of</strong><br />

689 Federal Office for the Environment, 2008, Guide to <strong>Waste</strong> [Online] (Updated 28 th February 2008).<br />

Available at: http://www.bafu.admin.ch/abfall/01472/index.html?lang=en [Accessed 10 th September<br />

2008].<br />

690 New Jersey <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environmental Protection (2006) New Jersey Generation, Disposal and<br />

Recycling Statistics, available online at<br />

http://www.state.nj.us/dep/dshw/recycling/stat_links/06%20Disposal_%20Rates_%20County.pdf.<br />

29/09/09


waste from manufacturing industries was recycled in 2005, and approximately 45 %<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste from institutions, trade and <strong>of</strong>fices. 691<br />

C&I waste constitutes approximately 16% <strong>of</strong>, for example, the German waste arisings;<br />

a contribution which is comparable to that <strong>of</strong> the householder, thus highlighting the<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> targeting the recycling <strong>of</strong> this waste stream for overall recycling rates<br />

and diversion from landfill.<br />

35.6 Implementation Costs<br />

A significant proportion <strong>of</strong> the implementation costs for C&I recycling will be covered<br />

by pre-paid disposal fees that are used to facilitate producer responsibility systems.<br />

Any additional costs will be the responsibility <strong>of</strong> the company, except where the<br />

municipality is required to provide separate recycling collections, though even in this<br />

instance the company will be likely to have to pay via business rates, or through a<br />

charging system.<br />

35.7 Complementary Policies<br />

See Section 34.8.<br />

35.8 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

See Section 34.9.<br />

35.9 Lessons Learned<br />

New Jersey currently requires businesses to arrange for the separate collection <strong>of</strong><br />

their waste streams, but does not provide sufficient financial support, leaving a large<br />

burden on businesses (as well as on the municipality as a whole). Landfill tax in New<br />

Jersey is only at $3 per ton (1.02 tonnes), providing insufficient funding to fully<br />

compensate mandatory recycling schemes. High landfill tax, and policies such as payby-use<br />

and producer responsibility schemes would provide additional financial<br />

support to the overall development <strong>of</strong> mandatory recycling schemes.<br />

35.10 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

569<br />

� Willingness <strong>of</strong> collectors to collect (including local authorities as collectors<br />

where it might be cost-effective to do so);<br />

� Supportive infrastructure such as Commercial and Industrial materials<br />

recovery facilities and facilities for composting / digestion for biowaste; and<br />

� An appreciation <strong>of</strong> why it is important to source-separate C&I waste (e.g.<br />

California).<br />

691 <strong>Waste</strong> Centre Denmark, [Online], <strong>Waste</strong> from Industry and Commerce. Available at<br />

http://www.wasteinfo.dk/waste+and+collection+companies/sources+types+and+fractions/waste+fro<br />

m+industry+and+commerce [Accessed 29 th September 2008].<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


36.0 Product Standards: Biowaste Treatment<br />

Products - <strong>International</strong><br />

36.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Standards are applied to the production <strong>of</strong> compost and digestate (hereafter referred<br />

to collectively as Biowaste Treatment Products or ‘BTPs’) in order to protect human<br />

health and the environment and in addition, to reduce transaction costs associated<br />

with compost sales through improving consumer confidence. Large quantities and<br />

repeated applications <strong>of</strong> BTPs, combined with the use <strong>of</strong> arable land for fodder<br />

production, ensures that the question <strong>of</strong> risk plays an important role in shaping<br />

regulation <strong>of</strong> compost production and use. 692 Alongside the setting <strong>of</strong> statutory<br />

standards associated with health and environmental protection, voluntary quality<br />

standards also exist in a number <strong>of</strong> countries that go beyond the precautionary<br />

requirements <strong>of</strong> the regulators, to ensure that the quality <strong>of</strong> the product meets the<br />

demands <strong>of</strong> the market i.e. is tailored to the end-user requirements. 693<br />

Standards are typically set according to a number <strong>of</strong> criteria including the feedstocks<br />

used, potentially-toxic elements (PTEs), organic contaminants, hygienisation<br />

principles and physical impurities. Underpinning the production <strong>of</strong> BTPs in the EU is<br />

the Animal By-Products Regulation (EC) n o 1774/2001 (the ‘ABPR’), notably amended<br />

by Regulation 208/2006, which provides detailed hygienisation rules (timetemperature<br />

regimes, process validation requirements, biological tests) for<br />

composting and biogas plants that treat animal by-products as part <strong>of</strong> their input<br />

material.<br />

36.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

Standards for BTPs exist throughout the EU, as well as in other parts <strong>of</strong> the world<br />

such as Australia, Canada, USA and New Zealand. Only Germany, Austria, the<br />

Netherlands, Italy, Switzerland, Sweden, and the Flemish region <strong>of</strong> Belgium can<br />

currently claim a mature compost market situation, though the situation in the UK is<br />

also developing rapidly. Despite their small number, these countries account for more<br />

than 2/3 <strong>of</strong> the biowaste treatment capacity in Europe. 692<br />

692 D. Hogg, D. Lister, J. Barth, E. Favoino and F. Amlinger (2009) Frameworks for Use <strong>of</strong> Compost in<br />

Agriculture in Europe, Final report for WRAP, January 2009<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/Eunomia_compost_in_agriculture_final_report.703534d2.6993.<br />

pdf .<br />

693 J. Barth, F. Amlinger, E. Favoino, S. Siebert, B. Kehres, R. Gottschall, M. Bieker, A. Löbig and W.<br />

Bidlingmaier (2008). Compost Production and Use in the EU. Report for the European Commission<br />

DG/JRC.<br />

570<br />

29/09/09


36.2.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

Table 36-1 Standard measures/requirements that apply to the production <strong>of</strong> BTPs<br />

in Europe [S = Statutory measure, V = Voluntary measure].<br />

Compost Production Standards<br />

Country<br />

Feedstock PTEs Organic Contaminants Hygienisation Physical Impurities<br />

s<br />

AT S S S (mixed waste only) S S<br />

BE S S S S<br />

BG<br />

CH S S S S<br />

CY<br />

CZ S S S S S<br />

DE S S S S<br />

DK S S S S<br />

EE S<br />

ES S S S S<br />

FI S S S S<br />

FR S S S S<br />

GR S<br />

HU S S S<br />

IE S S S S<br />

IT S S S S<br />

LT S S<br />

LU S S V S S<br />

LV S S<br />

MT<br />

NL S S S S<br />

PL S S S<br />

PT S<br />

SE V V S<br />

SI S<br />

SK V<br />

UK V S/V S V<br />

Canada S S V<br />

USA S S<br />

Australia S S<br />

New Zealand S S<br />

Source: Summarised from Hogg, D., Barth, J., Favoino, E., Centemero, M., Caimi, V., Amlinger, F.,<br />

Devliegher, W., Brinton, W. and Antler, S. (2002). Comparison <strong>of</strong> Compost Standards Within the EU,<br />

North America and Australasia. Report for the <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action Programme and D. Hogg,<br />

D. Lister, J. Barth, E. Favoino and F. Amlinger (2009) Frameworks for Use <strong>of</strong> Compost in Agriculture in<br />

Europe, Final report for WRAP, January 2009<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/Eunomia_compost_in_agriculture_final_report.703534d2.6993.<br />

pdf .<br />

571<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Due to the large number <strong>of</strong> countries that currently implement standards relating to<br />

BTPs, Table 36-1 summarises which countries apply which standard<br />

measures/restrictions as part <strong>of</strong> their policy on BTP production; the section is then<br />

broken down into a summary <strong>of</strong> country-specific characteristics for each <strong>of</strong> the<br />

measures that form part <strong>of</strong> the overall compost standard. Two key reports have been<br />

used in order to summarise policies related to compost quality worldwide. 694 695<br />

Additional references are provided throughout the document.<br />

Feedstocks<br />

The ABPR limits the materials that can be used in composting and biogas plants.<br />

572<br />

� Category 1 materials cannot be dealt with in composting or biogas plants;<br />

� Category 2 materials can be dealt with in composting or biogas plants if they<br />

are treated in a particular manner as identified in Article 13. Manure, digestive<br />

tract content separated from the digestive tract, milk and colostrums can be<br />

treated in composting and biogas plants in accordance with Articles 15 and<br />

18;<br />

� Category 3 materials can be dealt with in composting and biogas plants in a<br />

manner consistent with Article 15. Catering waste which is not <strong>of</strong> international<br />

origin can be dealt with in biogas and composting plants in line with rules <strong>of</strong><br />

national origin until rules are established under Article 33(2). This is an<br />

important exemption which most Member States have chosen to use to their<br />

advantage.<br />

Following on from these general guidelines, the majority <strong>of</strong> European countries have<br />

drawn up a positive list <strong>of</strong> materials that can be included as input materials, rather<br />

than listing which materials are excluded. In setting feedstock requirements, it can be<br />

expected that the resultant compost is more likely to consistently achieve the desired<br />

quality. In theory, this list should be different for composting plants compared to<br />

biogas plants, as biogas plants can accept wetter materials such as grease-trap fats.<br />

However in reality, such a split only exists in Austria, where a number <strong>of</strong> specified<br />

materials, such as rendered fats and glycerine residues, are restricted to anaerobic<br />

digestion plants. 696 Within the EU (plus Switzerland), 16 countries currently have<br />

statutory standards for those feedstock materials that can be used for BTPs, and a<br />

further 2 countries (Sweden and the United Kingdom) have voluntary standards. The<br />

most prominent waste groups excluded from the production <strong>of</strong> BTPs are municipal<br />

sewage sludge, mixed (not source-separated) municipal solid waste, paunch and<br />

manure. Source-separated MSW, in particular, is seen by a number <strong>of</strong> countries as a<br />

694 D. Hogg, J. Barth, E. Favoino, M. Centemero, V. Caimi, F. Amlinger, W. Devliegher, W. Brinton and S.<br />

Antler (2002). Comparison <strong>of</strong> Compost Standards Within the EU, North America and Australasia.<br />

Report for the <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action Programme.<br />

695 D. Hogg, D. Lister, J. Barth, E. Favoino and F. Amlinger (2009) Frameworks for Use <strong>of</strong> Compost in<br />

Agriculture in Europe, Final report for WRAP, January 2009<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/Eunomia_compost_in_agriculture_final_report.703534d2.6993.<br />

pdf .<br />

696 Communication with Josef Barth (Informa Organic <strong>Waste</strong> Consultants, Germany) 07/07/2008.<br />

29/09/09


solid pre-requisite for the production <strong>of</strong> BTPs, including in Flanders (Belgium),<br />

Germany, the Netherlands and Sweden, with sewage sludge also excluded from use<br />

as a feedstock in each <strong>of</strong> these countries.<br />

Potentially-Toxic Elements<br />

As detailed in Table 36-1, the majority <strong>of</strong> countries currently set limits on the amount<br />

<strong>of</strong> cadmium, chromium, copper, mercury, nickel, lead, zinc and arsenic present in<br />

compost. For most countries and most applications <strong>of</strong> compost, the following<br />

combination <strong>of</strong> heavy metals is allowed:<br />

573<br />

� ≤ 4 mg/kg d.m. cadmium<br />

� ≤ 400 mg/kg d.m. chromium<br />

� ≤ 600 mg/kg d.m. copper<br />

� ≤ 4 mg/kg d.m. mercury<br />

� ≤ 100 mg/kg d.m. nickel<br />

� ≤ 300 mg/kg d.m. lead<br />

� ≤ 1500 mg/kg d.m. zinc<br />

� 10-20 mg/kg d.m. arsenic<br />

Regarding PTEs, it is worth noting that following 10 years <strong>of</strong> experience in composting<br />

in the Netherlands, a change in legislation in 2007 resulted in less strict heavy metal<br />

thresholds, with experience instead recognising that nutrient content rather than<br />

heavy metal content was proving the limiting factor on compost use within the<br />

Netherlands. 697<br />

Organic Contaminants<br />

Several countries within the EU have established specific standards associated with<br />

organic contaminants in compost. In Austria and the Czech Republic, these limits<br />

relate to non-agricultural composts only, whereas in Belgium and Denmark the limits<br />

relate to compost/digestate produced from treated biowaste; in Luxembourg, the<br />

guide values are for both fresh and matured compost. Limit values are assigned for<br />

combinations <strong>of</strong> the following contaminants: polychlorinated biphenyls (PCB),<br />

polychlorinated dibenz<strong>of</strong>uran (PCCD/F), dioxins, polycyclic aromatic hydrocarbons<br />

(PAH), absorbable organic halogens (AOX), hydrocarbons, linear alkylbenzene<br />

sulphonates (LAS), nonylphenol (NPE) and di (2-ethylhexyl) phthalate (DEHP).<br />

Countries such as Germany, the Netherlands and Italy do not currently impose any<br />

organic-contaminant restrictions on their composts, due to the low levels <strong>of</strong> such<br />

697 F. Amlinger, E. Favoino, M. Pollak, S. Peyr, M. Centemero and V. Caima (2004) Heavy metals and<br />

organic compounds from wastes used as organic fertilisers, Study on behalf <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Commission, Directorate-General Environment, ENV .A.2,<br />

http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/waste/compost/index.htm<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


contaminants found in their composts 698 which they relate, at least in part, to the<br />

source-separated biowaste collections in their countries.<br />

Hygienisation<br />

Annex VI <strong>of</strong> the ABPR provides detailed hygienisation rules for composting and biogas<br />

plants that treat animal by-products in the EU. The general rules for Category 3<br />

material according to Annex VI are:<br />

574<br />

� The maximum particle size before the material enters the unit/composting<br />

reactor is 12 mm;<br />

� The minimum temperature for all material in the unit/reactor is 70°C; and<br />

� The minimum time at which all material must be at 70°C is 60 min.<br />

However, as stated in the ABP regulation, process validation may be used as an<br />

alternative treatment to fixed time-temperature regimes as long as it ensures the<br />

minimisation <strong>of</strong> biological risk for Category 3 materials. The process must result in a<br />

reduction <strong>of</strong> 5 log10 <strong>of</strong> Enterococcus faecalis or Salmonella Senftenberg (775W, H2S<br />

negative) and infectivity titre <strong>of</strong> thermo-resistant viruses such as parvovirus by at least<br />

3 log10, whenever such viruses are identified as a relevant hazard. In addition<br />

Escherichia coli or Enterococcae are to be used as indicator organisms for approval<br />

<strong>of</strong> the process and final BTP. A maximum number <strong>of</strong> bacteria in 1 g is set at 1,000 for<br />

4 out <strong>of</strong> 5 samples and only in 1 sample can the bacteria number can be between<br />

1,000 and 5,000. For the hygiene status <strong>of</strong> the product, Salmonella must be absent<br />

in 25 g.<br />

Annex VI does, however, show some deviations to the above rules. When manure or<br />

digestive tract content are the only ABP material being treated, the competent<br />

authority may also authorise the use <strong>of</strong> different specific requirements from those<br />

stated above, provided that they do not consider that the material presents a risk <strong>of</strong><br />

spreading disease and that the residues/compost are considered to be unprocessed<br />

material.<br />

In addition, the case <strong>of</strong> catering waste has always been a special one as far as the<br />

ABPR is concerned. Catering waste is defined in the ABP as all food waste originating<br />

in both commercial and household kitchens/facilities. From the outset, the ABPR<br />

effectively allowed Member States to set their own rules regarding Category 3<br />

catering waste which was not from means <strong>of</strong> transport operating internationally<br />

(Article 6(2)(g)). Thus, where catering waste is the only ABP being used as raw<br />

material in the composting or AD plant, the competent authority may authorise<br />

specific requirements other than those laid down in Annex VI <strong>of</strong> the ABPR.<br />

However, although the Articles in the ABPR exempt Category 3 catering waste that is<br />

not from means <strong>of</strong> transport operating internationally, Annex VI nonetheless<br />

comments on this waste category, stating:<br />

698 B. Deller, R. Kluge, M. Mokry, R. Bolduan and A. Trenkle (2008) Effects <strong>of</strong> Mid-Term Application <strong>of</strong><br />

Compost on Agricultural Soils in Field Trials <strong>of</strong> Practical Importance: Possible Risks. Compost and<br />

Digestate: Sustainability, Benefits, Impacts for the Environment and for Plant Production, Proceedings<br />

<strong>of</strong> the <strong>International</strong> Congress CODIS February 27-29, 2008.<br />

29/09/09


575<br />

However, pending the adoption <strong>of</strong> rules in accordance with Article 6(2)(g), the<br />

competent authority may, when catering waste is the only animal by-product<br />

used as raw material in a biogas or composting plant, authorise the use <strong>of</strong><br />

processing standards other than those laid down in paragraphs 12 and 13<br />

provided that they guarantee an equivalent effect regarding the reduction <strong>of</strong><br />

pathogens.<br />

Annex VI thus adds confusion to the processing requirements for Category 3 catering<br />

waste, particularly given that the amending Regulation 208/2006 inserted the<br />

process validation tests discussed above just before this paragraph, which had<br />

previously, in Regulation 1774/2001, followed paragraphs discussing temperature,<br />

time and particle size. Thus it is not clear to what the term ‘equivalent effect’ refers,<br />

and thus how it should be established and to what it is that ‘equivalence’ should be<br />

demonstrated.<br />

It is important to note that the ABP Regulation is currently being amended, with a<br />

draft proposal and a working document with annexes currently under discussion<br />

among stakeholders within the European community. Some commentators suggest<br />

that it is likely that the existing exemption for catering waste, giving Member States<br />

the possibility <strong>of</strong> setting national processing rules for catering waste, will be<br />

maintained. 699<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> countries have subsequently chosen the option <strong>of</strong> national regulations<br />

for catering waste rather than adopting the ‘70°C for 1 h’ processing standard set out<br />

under the ABPR. National regulations have been maintained mainly because in<br />

practice, composting and digestion plants have found it difficult to implement the<br />

Annex VI standard, particularly the 12 mm particle size requirement in composting<br />

plants. All EU MSs have some test for pathogens; however, with the exception <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Netherlands, the tests are set in terms <strong>of</strong> the presence <strong>of</strong> a given pathogen rather<br />

than in terms <strong>of</strong> the level <strong>of</strong> reduction in the presence <strong>of</strong> the pathogen. Annex VI <strong>of</strong><br />

the ABPR concentrates on the latter, but it is difficult to see why this should be the<br />

case from the perspective <strong>of</strong> the risks <strong>of</strong> using BTPs on land.<br />

Denmark, France, Germany and Italy have all maintained their pre-ABPR timetemperature<br />

regimes for catering waste. In addition, following amendment<br />

208/2006, the Netherlands has developed its own process validation and<br />

corresponding sampling regime which allows the spot test method to be used, in<br />

order to show a 5 log10 pathogen reduction in the BTPs produced from the plants.<br />

Only Belgium, Hungary, Latvia and Poland make use <strong>of</strong> the 70ºC for 1 h ABPR<br />

hygienisation process for all ABP input materials, including catering wastes. For<br />

Belgium/Flanders, however, the catering waste regulation is not considered relevant<br />

for the majority <strong>of</strong> plants whose feedstock is vegetable, fruit and garden (VFG) waste,<br />

with animal by-products excluded in the separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste.<br />

For the remaining Category 3 waste (i.e. plants not solely accepting catering wastes),<br />

the majority <strong>of</strong> EU MS have fully-implemented the Annex VI ABP regulations (i.e. 70ºC<br />

699 F. Amlinger (2008) Implementation <strong>of</strong> the Animal By-Products Regulation (EC) no 1774/2001 in EU<br />

Member States, Presentation at Orbit2008, 13-15th October 2008, Wageningen, The Netherlands.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


for 1 h or equivalent process validation), including Belgium, Germany, Italy, the<br />

Netherlands, Sweden and the United Kingdom. Likewise for manure, the ABP<br />

regulations are followed in Belgium, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Latvia, the<br />

Netherlands and Sweden; in the UK the 70ºC for 1 hour standard has to be followed<br />

only where the manure is to be exported from the farm.<br />

Outside <strong>of</strong> the EU, Canada has a statutory time-temperature regime for compost,<br />

requiring 55ºC for 3 days in an in-vessel composting plant or aerated static pile, and<br />

55ºC for 15 days in open windrow. The USA also requires a temperature <strong>of</strong> 55ºC, but<br />

for either 5 days in an in-vessel facility or 15 days in open windrow. In Australia, three<br />

turns <strong>of</strong> the windrow are required, with the requirement that the temperature reaches<br />

55ºC for 3 days prior to each turn.<br />

Physical Impurities<br />

Plastics, metals and glass are the three main impurities limited in compost standards.<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> EU countries impose limits <strong>of</strong> some kind on physical impurities, but<br />

the limits may vary from a combined maximum concentration <strong>of</strong> plastics, metals and<br />

glass greater than a given particle size (Germany, Latvia and Spain), to individual<br />

limits set for each type <strong>of</strong> impurity (Austria, Italy).<br />

Land Application<br />

The main restrictions on the use <strong>of</strong> compost relate to the amount <strong>of</strong> nutrients and/or<br />

PTEs that can be applied to land in any one year. In Europe, the amount <strong>of</strong> nutrients is<br />

governed to a large extent by the EU Nitrate Directive, with a maximum application <strong>of</strong><br />

170 kg N/ha/y, and 30-40 kg P/ha/y in Nitrate Vulnerable Zones (NVZ) in most<br />

countries. In addition, countries such as Austria, Belgium and Italy are increasingly<br />

taking account <strong>of</strong> the availability <strong>of</strong> nitrogen and phosphorus in their application<br />

rates. This would tend to allow higher applications <strong>of</strong> compost than might otherwise<br />

be the case, for the simple reason that nitrogen in compost is not as readily-available<br />

to plants (or for leaching into groundwater) compared with nitrogen in synthetic<br />

fertiliser.<br />

In a number <strong>of</strong> countries, restrictions on compost use have also been determined<br />

according to the class <strong>of</strong> compost produced. For example, in Austria there are three<br />

classes <strong>of</strong> compost that can be produced:<br />

576<br />

� Category 1 material (Biowaste) <strong>of</strong> A+ quality (lowest heavy metal limits);<br />

� Category 1 material and Category 2 material (quality sewage sludge<br />

determined by heavy metal limits) <strong>of</strong> A+ and A quality (low heavy metal limits);<br />

and<br />

� Category 3 material (mixed MSW) <strong>of</strong> Quality B (highest heavy metal limits).<br />

Only the former two classes can be used on agricultural land (with the first class being<br />

suitable for organic farming as well); the final class can only be used for nonagricultural<br />

applications such as landscaping and land reclamation.<br />

Quality Assurance Schemes<br />

In addition to the regulations listed above regarding compost standards, the use <strong>of</strong><br />

Quality Assurance Schemes (QASs) within a number <strong>of</strong> European countries has played<br />

a key role in improving the status <strong>of</strong> compost in the eyes <strong>of</strong> the end users. QASs ‘start’<br />

29/09/09


where the abovementioned statutory standards that follow the precautionary principle<br />

usually end, 700 looking to address issues related to the marketing <strong>of</strong> BTPs and<br />

improve end-user confidence in the products. QASs can include public relations work,<br />

detailed declarations <strong>of</strong> compost characteristics so that end users understand the<br />

appropriateness <strong>of</strong> a given BTP for their purposes and verification/monitoring <strong>of</strong><br />

standardised products by independent organisations. QASs are well-established in<br />

countries such as Austria, Belgium, Germany, Italy and Sweden. Though not<br />

specifically a policy, QASs further increase the recycling potential for biodegradable<br />

material by strengthening the markets for BTPs.<br />

36.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The key organisations involved in implementing this policy are:<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment/Agriculture (National Government)<br />

577<br />

� Setting ‘precautionary’ compost standards and limit values.<br />

Quality Assurance Schemes<br />

� As stated above, QASs ‘start’ where the statutory standards that follow the<br />

precautionary principle usually end, looking to address issues related to the<br />

marketing <strong>of</strong> BTPs and improve end-user confidence in the products.<br />

Laboratories<br />

� Analysing the samples from the compost and AD plants to ensure they meet<br />

the required statutory / voluntary standards as applicable.<br />

Compost and AD plant operators<br />

� Ensure that the compost/AD standards are met, particularly regarding<br />

feedstock materials and hygienisation requirements.<br />

� Implement new advances in technology to improve the composting/AD<br />

process, and ensure that issues such as odours associated with plants are<br />

kept to a minimum.<br />

Organic waste collectors<br />

� Arrange collection <strong>of</strong> municipal biodegradable waste feedstock for composting<br />

and AD. Typically involves the local government.<br />

Organic waste sources<br />

� Source-separation <strong>of</strong> biowaste by householders and businesses for collection<br />

to ensure quality input materials for composting/AD.<br />

End-users<br />

700 D. Hogg, J. Barth, E. Favoino, M. Centemero, V. Caimi, F. Amlinger, W. Devliegher, W. Brinton and S.<br />

Antler (2002). Comparison <strong>of</strong> Compost Standards Within the EU, North America and Australasia.<br />

Report for the <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action Programme.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Others<br />

578<br />

� In order that agricultural land in particular becomes a viable market, farming<br />

communities must be convinced that the use <strong>of</strong> BTPs is beneficial to them and<br />

does not bring adverse health or environmental consequences.<br />

� Farmers <strong>of</strong>ten set up AD plants on their own farms at a smaller-scale to<br />

process slurries and to provide energy. In Austria, for example, more than 110<br />

farm-based biogas plants were in operation in 2002. It should be noted that<br />

biogas plants in Austria that use organic waste have a higher return on the<br />

electricity that they produce than those which ferment only agricultural<br />

feedstock. In addition, farm-based AD plants are also regulated by the Green<br />

Electricity Act 2002 for 13 years, ensuring certainty for long-terms strategies<br />

on plant investments. 701<br />

� Farmers must also abide by application limits imposed on their land.<br />

� Other markets that use BTPs e.g. horticulture and landscaping.<br />

� Scientific community undertaking studies to test the ‘risk’ associated with use<br />

<strong>of</strong> BTPs, particularly in agriculture e.g. the strategic Miljøforsknings programme<br />

in Denmark. 702<br />

36.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

F. Amlinger, S. Peyr, J. Geszti, P. Dreher, K. Weinfurtner and S. Nortcliff (2007)<br />

Beneficial Effects <strong>of</strong> Compost Application on Fertility and Productivity <strong>of</strong> Soils:<br />

Literature Study. Report produced for the Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry,<br />

Environment and Water <strong>Management</strong>, Austria.<br />

J. Barth, F. Amlinger, E. Favoino, S. Siebert, B. Kehres, R. Gottschall, M. Bieker, A.<br />

Löbig and W. Bidlingmaier (2008). Compost Production and Use in the EU. Report for<br />

the European Commission DG/JRC.<br />

D. Hogg, J. Barth, E. Favoino, M. Centemero, V. Caimi, F. Amlinger, W. Devliegher, W.<br />

Brinton and S. Antler (2002). Comparison <strong>of</strong> Compost Standards Within the EU, North<br />

America and Australasia. Report for the <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action Programme.<br />

D. Hogg, D. Lister, J. Barth, E. Favoino and F. Amlinger (2009) Frameworks for Use <strong>of</strong><br />

Compost in Agriculture in Europe, Final report for WRAP, January 2009<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/Eunomia_compost_in_agriculture_final_report.7<br />

03534d2.6993.pdf .<br />

701 C. Walla and W. Schneeberger (2003) Survey Of Farm Biogas Plants With Combined Heat And<br />

Power Production In Austria, <strong>International</strong> Nordic Bioenergy 2003 Conference.<br />

702 Center for Bæredygtig Arealanvendelse og Forvaltning af Miljøfremmede St<strong>of</strong>fer, Kulst<strong>of</strong> og<br />

Kvælst<strong>of</strong>, Aalborg Universitet. (2002). Det Strategiske Miljøforskningsprogram 1997-2000,<br />

Slutrapport. Http://Info.Au.Dk/Smp/Smp_Dk/Publikationer/Slutrapport/KH%20-%20Slutrapport.Pdf<br />

29/09/09


36.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The environmental benefits associated with the implementation <strong>of</strong> standards for the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> compost and digestate are several fold, ranging from the key<br />

requirement <strong>of</strong> minimising risk to both human and animal health associated with the<br />

application <strong>of</strong> BTPs to land, to the positive benefits related to the use <strong>of</strong> BTPs as a<br />

fertiliser. In limiting the presence <strong>of</strong> contaminants such as PTEs and organic<br />

contaminants in BTPs, these contaminants are also subsequently limited/ prevented<br />

from building up in both the soil and surrounding water supplies when applied to the<br />

land, and are thus prevented from building up within crops and animals based on that<br />

land. Regarding positive soil-related benefits, these include the following: 703<br />

579<br />

� An increase in soil organic matter, and hence in soil quality during long-term (6<br />

years or more) compost application trials, particularly when applying mature<br />

rather than fresh compost to the soil ;<br />

� After 3 to 6 years <strong>of</strong> application, a positive yield effect on a variety <strong>of</strong> crops<br />

and a more stable yield (with compost able to balance yearly climatic<br />

variations) compared to unfertilised and mineral-fertiliser control plots;<br />

� A constant increase in total and available stock <strong>of</strong> macro-nutrients and<br />

calcium in the soil, enabling the substitution <strong>of</strong> mineral fertilisers for compost;<br />

and<br />

� Suppression <strong>of</strong> soil-born plant diseases by mature compost application.<br />

Compost must be mature (i.e. sufficiently stabilised) to ensure that pathogens<br />

are not stimulated by readily assimilable carbon.<br />

In addition to the benefits to land such as enhanced soil quality and to the reduction<br />

in the need for mineral fertilisers, the use <strong>of</strong> compost standards and the resultant<br />

increase in organic waste recycling diverts organic waste away from landfill. This<br />

diversion is important, because it leads to a reduction in the production <strong>of</strong><br />

greenhouse gases from landfill sites, as well as producing BTPs and energy in the<br />

composting and AD processes. The use <strong>of</strong> organic waste to produce energy via<br />

anaerobic digestion also thus reduces our reliance on primary fuel sources.<br />

Regarding the current collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> organic waste, a study by Barth et al.<br />

(2008) 704 looking at compost production and use within the EU, found that the<br />

collected and treated amounts <strong>of</strong> organic material vary widely from country to country.<br />

The study found that, <strong>of</strong> the estimated 80 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> potentially-recoverable<br />

organic waste, around 30 % is currently source-separated and treated via<br />

composting/AD, resulting in the production <strong>of</strong> 10.5 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> compost<br />

703 F. Amlinger, S. Peyr, J. Geszti, P. Dreher, K. Weinfurtner and S. Nortcliff (2007) Beneficial Effects <strong>of</strong><br />

Compost Application on Fertility and Productivity <strong>of</strong> Soils: Literature Study. Report produced for the<br />

Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry, Environment and Water <strong>Management</strong>, Austria.<br />

704 J. Barth, F. Amlinger, E. Favoino, S. Siebert, B. Kehres, R. Gottschall, M. Bieker, A. Löbig and W.<br />

Bidlingmaier (2008). Compost Production and Use in the EU. Report for the European Commission<br />

DG/JRC.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


throughout Europe. In addition, some MS also produce around 1.4 million tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

compost from sewage sludge and a similar amount <strong>of</strong> compost from mixed waste.<br />

Due to a general lack <strong>of</strong> consistently reported data on organic waste arisings, the<br />

potentially-recoverable organic waste calculation is based on 150 kg per inhabitant<br />

per year and includes source-separated kitchen and garden waste from households,<br />

park and garden waste from public estates and industrial wastes. This figure appears<br />

to be realistic given the amounts already collected in well-established biowaste<br />

management systems such as Austria, Germany and the Netherlands, though<br />

particularly for parks and non-household garden waste, data is not sufficient to be<br />

able to say with any certainty the amount <strong>of</strong> this collected waste that will end up in<br />

composting/AD facilities.<br />

Table 36-2 illustrates how effectively the EU MSs separately collect the available<br />

organic fraction <strong>of</strong> their national waste arisings for recycling purposes; the<br />

Netherlands exceeds their potential according to the 150 kg per inhabitant per year<br />

calculation, and Austria, Germany, Denmark, Finland and Luxembourg are all<br />

relatively successful in terms <strong>of</strong> reaching their potential. These countries all have<br />

reasonably well-developed compost/AD industries with statutory regulations<br />

surrounding compost production; in addition, all except Denmark and Finland also<br />

have a QAS to support the statutory framework. It should be noted that Denmark,<br />

Finland and the Netherlands owe a large proportion <strong>of</strong> their success to extensive<br />

garden waste collection and composting.<br />

The success <strong>of</strong> minimum compost standards can also be measured by examining<br />

whether any perception issues related to the use <strong>of</strong> compost have arisen in the enduser<br />

markets for BTPs. The end-user market shares for compost (Table 36-3)<br />

illustrate that a notable portion <strong>of</strong> compost is used in the higher-price markets such<br />

as horticulture and greenhouse production, illustrating confidence <strong>of</strong> the market in<br />

the product. In addition, Table 36-3 illustrates the dominant use <strong>of</strong> compost in<br />

agriculture across the EU. Hogg et al. (2008) 705 recently acquired information on<br />

perception issues related to use <strong>of</strong> BTPs in the agricultural sector via a series <strong>of</strong><br />

questionnaires sent to national experts across the EU. In those countries with mature<br />

composting markets and a solid statutory compost quality base, perception issues<br />

have been minimal both from the perspective <strong>of</strong> the farmer and <strong>of</strong> the householder.<br />

For example, in Austria, householders have taken a very positive approach to organics<br />

recycling, and open discussions between the Ministry and Chamber <strong>of</strong> Agriculture on<br />

heavy metal and nutrient loads in agricultural soils have ensured that the market has<br />

confidence in the thresholds that have been set. Following introduction <strong>of</strong> the ABPR,<br />

farmers were actually <strong>of</strong>fended at the implied need for additional requirements,<br />

particularly as a large amount <strong>of</strong> composting takes place on-farm in Austria, with<br />

farmers sometimes also being involved in the collection <strong>of</strong> household biowaste for<br />

their facilities.<br />

705 D. Hogg, D. Lister, J. Barth, E. Favoino and F. Amlinger (2009) Frameworks for Use <strong>of</strong> Compost in<br />

Agriculture in Europe, Final report for WRAP, January 2009<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/Eunomia_compost_in_agriculture_final_report.703534d2.6993.<br />

pdf .<br />

580<br />

29/09/09


Table 36-2 Amount (‘000 tonnes) <strong>of</strong> separately collected and composted/digested<br />

biowaste and green waste in the EU (2005)<br />

Potential Potential Potential quantities<br />

quantities<br />

Separately Separately Separately collected<br />

collected<br />

[without [without home home home composting] composting] (3)<br />

Separately Separately<br />

Separately<br />

Collected<br />

Collected<br />

MS<br />

Tot Total Tot al MSW<br />

(1) Bio-<br />

waste<br />

waste<br />

Green<br />

Green<br />

waste<br />

waste<br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

(2)<br />

Biowaste Biowaste<br />

Biowaste<br />

Green<br />

Green<br />

waste waste<br />

waste<br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

Biowaste<br />

Biowaste<br />

[% [% <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> total<br />

total<br />

potentially-<br />

potentially<br />

recoverable]<br />

recoverable]<br />

recoverable]<br />

AT AT<br />

3,419 750 950 1,700 546 950 1,496 88%<br />

BE 4,847 n.d. n.d. 2,573 n.d. n.d. 885 34%<br />

BG* BG* 3,593 n.d. n.d. 1,164 0 0 0 0%<br />

CY* CY* 554 n.d. n.d. 112 0 0 0 0%<br />

CZ CZ<br />

3979 1354 180 1534 10 123 133 9%<br />

DE DE<br />

37,266 8,000 8,000 16,000 4,084 4,254 8,338 52%<br />

DK 3,988 433 750 1,183 38 737 775 66%<br />

EE EE<br />

556 195 130 325 0 0 0 0%<br />

ES* ES* 25,694 n.d. n.d. 6,456 n.d. n.d. 308 5%<br />

FI* 2,451 n.d. n.d. 785 350 100 450 57%<br />

FR* FR* FR* 46,000 n.d. n.d. 9,378 300 2,400 2,700 29%<br />

GR* GR* 4,854 n.d. n.d. 1,662 0 2 2 0%<br />

HU* HU* 4,446 n.d. n.d. 1,515 n.d. n.d. 127 8%<br />

IE IE (2007) (4) 3,174 n.d. n.d. 918 n.d n.d 79 8.6%<br />

IT 31,687 n.d. n.d. 8,700 2,050 380 2,430 28%<br />

LT* 1,295 n.d. n.d. 514 0 0 0 0%<br />

LU* LU* 321 n.d. n.d. 68 n.d. n.d. 52 76%<br />

LV* LV* 715 n.d. n.d. 346 0 0 0 0%<br />

MT* MT* 246 n.d. n.d. 60 0 0 0 0%<br />

NL* NL* 10,900 n.d. n.d. 2,446 1,656 1,700 3,356 137%<br />

PL* PL* 9,353 n.d. n.d. 5,726 n.d. n.d. 70 1%<br />

PT 4,696 n.d. n.d. 1,579 24 10 34 2%<br />

RO* RO* 8,274 n.d. n.d. 3,249 0 0 0 0%<br />

SE* SE* 4,343 n.d. n.d. 1,352 125 250 375 28%<br />

SI* 845 n.d. n.d. 300 0 0 0 0%<br />

SK* SK* 1,558 n.d. n.d. 808 5 68 73 9%<br />

UK* UK* 35,075 n.d. n.d. 9,009 n.d. n.d. 1,872 21%<br />

EU27 EU27 257,947 80,101 23,598 23,598 29.5%<br />

(1) Source: Eurostat website (http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu)<br />

(2) In most cases individual estimations by national experts were missing. For all MS marked with an<br />

‘*’ the realistic potential <strong>of</strong> biowaste and green waste collection is based on the assumption <strong>of</strong> 150<br />

kg/Inh*y<br />

(3) The estimation <strong>of</strong> currently collected biowaste and green waste has been provided by national<br />

experts contacted during the elaboration <strong>of</strong> this study. The reference year was 2005.<br />

(4) Environmental Protection Agency (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007.<br />

Source: Barth, J., Amlinger, F., Favoino, E., Siebert, S., Kehres, B., Gottschall, R., Bieker, M., Löbig, A.<br />

and Bidlingmaier, W. (2008). Compost Production and Use in the EU. Report for the European<br />

Commission DG/JRC.<br />

581<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 36-3 Compost Market Shares <strong>of</strong> Various Sectors within the EU (%)<br />

582<br />

Country Country AT AT BE/Fl BE/Fl BE/Fl DE DE ES<br />

29/09/09<br />

ES 1) FI<br />

FI FR<br />

FR<br />

FR 2) HU<br />

HU IE IE IT<br />

NL<br />

NL<br />

bio bio- bio<br />

waste<br />

waste<br />

NL NL 1)<br />

green<br />

green<br />

waste waste PL<br />

PL<br />

PL 2) SE<br />

SE UK<br />

Sect Sector Sect or 2003 2005 2005 2006 2005 2005 2005 2006 2003 2005 2005 2005 2005 2005 %<br />

Mean<br />

Mean<br />

EU<br />

EU<br />

Agriculture Agriculture 40.0 1.0 53.4 88.0 20.0 71.0 55.0 37.0 51.0 74.8 44.4 - - 30.0 48.0<br />

48.0<br />

Horticulture Horticulture Horticulture &<br />

&<br />

green green house<br />

house<br />

production<br />

production<br />

10.0 1.0 3.9 8.0 - 25.0 15.0 3.0 - - 15.5 - 5.0 13.0 11.3<br />

11.3<br />

La Landscaping<br />

La ndscaping 15.0 22.0 15.9 4.0 20.0 - 10.0 6.0 6.0 3.6 12.3 - 20.0 14.0 12.4<br />

12.4<br />

Blends Blends 15.0 6.0 13.6 - 10.0 - - 16.0 15.0 5.1 - 2.0 10.3<br />

10.3<br />

Soil Soil mixing<br />

mixing<br />

companies<br />

companies<br />

2.0 21.0 - - - - - - - - 9.4 - 10.0 - 10.6<br />

10.6<br />

Wholesalers Wholesalers - 9.0 - - - - - - - - 5.2 - 15.0 - 9.7<br />

Hobby obby<br />

gardening<br />

gardening<br />

Land Land resto resto- resto<br />

ration ration and<br />

and<br />

landfill landfill landfill cover<br />

cover<br />

15.0 20.0 11.9 - - 4.0 5.0 - 27.0 1.1 2.3 - 10.0 25.0 11.0<br />

11.0<br />

2.0 1.0 - - 50.0 - 15.0 38 2.0 - - 100.0 40.0 16.0 26.4<br />

26.4<br />

Export Export 1.0 7.0 - - - - - - - 5.5 5.0 - - - 4.6 4.6<br />

Others Others Others - 2.0 1.3 - - - - - - - 0.8 - - - 1.4 1.4<br />

1) Green waste compost; 2) Mainly mixed waste compost<br />

Source: Barth, J., Amlinger, F., Favoino, E., Siebert, S., Kehres, B., Gottschall, R., Bieker, M., Löbig, A.<br />

and Bidlingmaier, W. (2008). Compost Production and Use in the EU. Report for the European<br />

Commission DG/JRC.<br />

In Denmark, the key perception issue has been to ensure that all consumers are<br />

happy that they are not purchasing anything which poses a risk to human or animal<br />

health, with policy around compost standards designed to address these concerns.<br />

Additional obstacles to further increases in composting have mostly related to the<br />

successful collection <strong>of</strong> source-separated biowaste, and in overcoming the short-term<br />

slower release <strong>of</strong> nitrogen from compost compared to from mineral fertilisers. 706 It is<br />

interesting to note that the overall proportion <strong>of</strong> sewage sludge being used in<br />

composting/AD plants in Denmark is decreasing over time in favour <strong>of</strong> source-<br />

706 J. Luxhøi, P.H.B. Poulsen, J. Møller and J. Magid (2008). Quality Parameters <strong>of</strong> Compost Amended<br />

with Chitin. Compost and Digestate: Sustainability, Benefits, Impacts for the Environment and for Plant<br />

Production, Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the <strong>International</strong> Congress CODIS February 27-29, 2008.


separated kitchen and garden waste, because the outputs achieved from sewage<br />

sludge no longer achieve the standards that farmers demand to maintain an<br />

ecologically safe farm.<br />

In Germany, once it was made clear that composts were no longer to be derived from<br />

mixed wastes, a positive perception <strong>of</strong> compost was formed in those BTP markets<br />

other than agriculture, especially in the landscaping and growing media sector.<br />

Representatives from business sectors such as landscaping and growing media were<br />

substantially involved in the foundation <strong>of</strong> the German Compost Quality Assurance<br />

Organisation and the development <strong>of</strong> standards and application recommendations. In<br />

the agricultural sector, the agricultural branch organisation and authorities were<br />

initially typically against the use <strong>of</strong> compost in agriculture, with political rivalry<br />

between the Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment (pro- compost use) and the Ministry <strong>of</strong><br />

Agriculture (against compost use) fuelling the debate. Nevertheless, personal<br />

relationships between compost producers and farmers helped to build up the<br />

necessary confidence for the use <strong>of</strong> compost in agricultural practice.<br />

Continuing development <strong>of</strong> trust between compost producers and farmers, success<br />

stories within the farming sector, and the strictly quality-oriented work <strong>of</strong> the German<br />

QAS all helped build confidence within the agricultural sector on the use <strong>of</strong> compost.<br />

Nevertheless, it took nearly 10 years before the first generally available brochure for<br />

compost application in agriculture was published. Confidence was, nonetheless,<br />

sufficient that even when animal protein was found in sugar beets and the sugar beet<br />

organisation subsequently forbade their member farms to use compost (a loss <strong>of</strong><br />

30% <strong>of</strong> the German compost market), the sugar beet industry remained open to<br />

discussions with the compost sector, and to the outcomes <strong>of</strong> research, which finally<br />

identified the source <strong>of</strong> the protein as coming not from compost, but from rodents<br />

living on the sugar beet storage piles at the border <strong>of</strong> the fields.<br />

There has been a particularly strong focus on AD technology in Sweden due to<br />

national support and a demand for upgraded biogas as a vehicle fuel. There is a<br />

positive awareness <strong>of</strong> the need to recycle and re-use organic waste to reduce fossil<br />

fuel requirements and climatic impacts. The majority <strong>of</strong> BTP standards in Sweden are<br />

based on voluntary agreements rather than statutory regulations, due to the high<br />

quality BTPs that are produced in Sweden, which in turn, are related to input material<br />

controls. Farmers have used 98 % <strong>of</strong> digestate outputs on agricultural land in 2008,<br />

illustrating the faith that farmers have in this product as being ecologically safe; in<br />

contrast, the majority <strong>of</strong> compost outputs are used by the growing media/substrate<br />

market due to economic viability.<br />

36.6 Implementation Costs<br />

A variety <strong>of</strong> factors contribute to the implementation costs <strong>of</strong> composting/AD<br />

standards; these will include;<br />

583<br />

� Feedstock collection costs to ensure minimal contamination;<br />

� Monitoring costs <strong>of</strong> composting/AD process and product;<br />

� Technology used (composter/AD plant type); and<br />

� Marketing costs for the product.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Within the compost industry, implementation costs across the EU are predominantly<br />

met via income from gate fees and energy production, rather than reflecting the<br />

‘actual’ value <strong>of</strong> the compost in relation to market demand and production costs.<br />

Only very few companies have developed their local market sufficiently in order that<br />

their compost sales actually contribute to their economic success.<br />

36.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

584<br />

� The development <strong>of</strong> separate collection systems in order to increase the<br />

material available for composting/ AD and reduce the presence <strong>of</strong><br />

contaminants and physical impurities in the feedstock for BTP production, The<br />

aforementioned example <strong>of</strong> Denmark (Section 32.4) illustrates a move away<br />

from the use <strong>of</strong> sewage sludge as an input material and the move instead<br />

towards source-separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste in order to meet the required<br />

quality for end-user markets.<br />

� Development <strong>of</strong> laboratory testing/procedures to ensure that the BTPs meet<br />

the desired quality requirements for the end-user.<br />

36.8 Complementary Policies<br />

� Landfill Directive; specifies the requirement to divert biodegradable waste<br />

from landfill, hence promoting the need for the separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste<br />

and subsequent compost/AD processes.<br />

� Nitrate Directive; specifies maximum application rates <strong>of</strong> nitrogen in nitratevulnerable<br />

zones, hence limits the application <strong>of</strong> BTPs accordingly.<br />

� Mandates to separate organic wastes at source (see Annexes 34.0 and 35.0);<br />

� Energy tariffs and the Renewables Obligation Certificate (ROCs); as noted in<br />

Section 36.3, those AD plants in Austria that use organic waste as well as<br />

agricultural feedstocks have a higher return on the electricity that they<br />

produce than those which ferment only agricultural feedstock. In addition,<br />

farm-based AD plants are also regulated by the Green Electricity Act 2002 for<br />

13 years, ensuring certainty for long-terms strategies on plant investments. 707<br />

In the United Kingdom, Renewables Obligation Certificates are <strong>of</strong>fered to<br />

renewable electricity generators for every MWh <strong>of</strong> electricity generated which<br />

can then be sold to other energy suppliers in order to help them fulfil their<br />

renewable energy obligation. Double ROCs are currently being considered for<br />

the production <strong>of</strong> electricity from anaerobic digestion plants. 708<br />

707 C. Walla and W. Schneeberger (2003) Survey Of Farm Biogas Plants With Combined Heat And<br />

Power Production In Austria, <strong>International</strong> Nordic Bioenergy 2003 Conference.<br />

708 UK Trade and Investment Services (2007) UK Government Builds on Renewable Energy Incentives,<br />

available at http://www.ukinvest.gov.uk/feature/4014905/en-GB.html.<br />

29/09/09


36.9 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The use <strong>of</strong> minimum standards and QASs associated with BTPs has allowed countries<br />

to market waste as a product following treatment, thus allowing it to compete in<br />

markets with synthetic fertilisers. However, as already discussed in Section 36.6,<br />

implementation costs across the EU are predominantly met via income from gate fees<br />

and energy sales rather than reflecting the ‘actual’ value <strong>of</strong> the compost in relation to<br />

market demand and production costs. Several companies have, nonetheless,<br />

developed their local market sufficiently in order that their compost sales actually<br />

contribute to their economic success. In addition, particularly in those countries that<br />

have a more mature compost market, there is greater economic incentive to enter<br />

into the revenue-oriented higher price markets. In order that the end-user has<br />

sufficient confidence in the product, these markets require that stringent QAS<br />

standards are met. Without such standards, the majority <strong>of</strong> trading would only occur<br />

on a more personal basis between, for example, farmers and the local community.<br />

Prices differ quite significantly from country to country, depending mainly on the<br />

marketing strategies <strong>of</strong> the plants. A number <strong>of</strong> plants (predominantly municipalityowned)<br />

obscure the market, because they exist not to make pr<strong>of</strong>it, but to encourage<br />

and facilitate organics recycling <strong>of</strong> municipal waste. According to Barth et al.<br />

(2008) 709 , detailed evaluation <strong>of</strong> German and Belgian compost markets found that<br />

compost prices ranged from €0 to €29 per tonne for most end-user markets.<br />

36.10 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Monitoring <strong>of</strong> compost/AD plants to ensure that they deliver the required standards is<br />

typically undertaken directly by local government bodies; for example, in Germany, the<br />

local EPAs are the competent authorities for the approval, control and monitoring <strong>of</strong><br />

the operation <strong>of</strong> the treatment plants. 710 In Denmark, the Danish Plant Directorate<br />

supervises the quality <strong>of</strong> products from public plants and the municipalities are<br />

charged with supervising the land-use <strong>of</strong> those products. In addition, for QAS<br />

schemes there typically exists additional monitoring; using Germany as an example,<br />

there is a step-by-step mechanism for applying sanctions where:<br />

585<br />

Step1: Step1: Non-fulfilment is registered: Following registration, written notification<br />

will be sent to the treatment plant, giving a time period (e.g. 3-months) for<br />

rectifying problems;<br />

Step Step 2: 2: Demands are still not fulfilled: The quality label is suspended for a<br />

limited time, in which the treatment plant may not use the quality<br />

label/certification. The monitoring system continues and the treatment plant<br />

has to fulfil all requirements over a further period. If there are no problems in<br />

709 J. Barth, F. Amlinger, E. Favoino, S. Siebert, B. Kehres, R. Gottschall, M. Bieker, A. Löbig and W.<br />

Bidlingmaier (2008). Compost Production and Use in the EU. Report for the European Commission<br />

DG/JRC.<br />

710 <strong>International</strong> Solid <strong>Waste</strong> Association. (2006) Biological <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment Survey. Edited by W.<br />

Rogalski and C. F. Schleiss.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


586<br />

29/09/09<br />

this respect, then after this period has elapsed, the quality label can be regranted;<br />

Step Step Step 3: 3: 3: If there are still any problems: The Quality Label will be withdrawn. If<br />

the plant wishes to participate again in the QAS, they have to re-apply for the<br />

Quality Label and re-submit to the approval procedure.<br />

While Step 1 can be an automatic procedure, the second step might be discussed<br />

and decided within the committee <strong>of</strong> independent experts <strong>of</strong> the QAS. The quality<br />

assurance/certification has to have a kind <strong>of</strong> an <strong>of</strong>ficial status, as withdrawal affects<br />

the economic prospects <strong>of</strong> the compost plant. 711<br />

36.11 Lessons Learned<br />

Feedstocks and maximum environmental benefits<br />

A study undertaken by Eunomia illustrates that the ability to maximise environmental<br />

benefits associated with the collection <strong>of</strong> household kitchen and garden waste is<br />

most effective when these are collected separately, with the majority <strong>of</strong> kitchen waste<br />

able to be processed via anaerobic digestion to produce energy and digestate (which<br />

could subsequently be applied to land as a nutrient source), and the garden waste<br />

treated via windrow composting to minimise costs. 712 This example illustrates the<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> defining input materials and collection systems in determining the<br />

subsequent environmental benefits associated with compost production.<br />

Hygienisation requirements<br />

The default 12 mm particle size required prior to material entering the reactor/unit<br />

according to the ABPR 208/2006 has created difficulties in practice for many<br />

composting plants. In Finland, for example, the compost had to be screened after 10<br />

days and the composting process then started again on the finer material in order to<br />

meet this requirement. Finland has subsequently changed its hygienisation process<br />

for catering wastes, allowing a maximum particle size <strong>of</strong> 40 mm and timetemperature<br />

requirements <strong>of</strong> 60 ºC for 14 days or 65 ºC for 7 days, with a growing<br />

number <strong>of</strong> plants opting to meet their hygienisation requirements via process<br />

validation.<br />

End-User confidence in the product<br />

Switzerland provides an example <strong>of</strong> the need to ensure confidence <strong>of</strong> farmers in BTPs<br />

in order for the closed-loop recycling <strong>of</strong> organic wastes to work effectively. Back in<br />

2002 and 2003, the agricultural sector was becoming nervous regarding the use <strong>of</strong><br />

sewage sludge on their land because <strong>of</strong> Bovine spongiform encephalopathy reports;<br />

many long-term users <strong>of</strong> sewage sludge rapidly lost their confidence in the quality the<br />

711 D. Hogg, J. Barth, E. Favoino, M. Centemero, V. Caimi, F. Amlinger, W. Devliegher, W. Brinton and S.<br />

Antler (2002). Comparison <strong>of</strong> Compost Standards Within the EU, North America and Australasia.<br />

Report for the <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action Programme.<br />

712 Eunomia (2007) Dealing with Food <strong>Waste</strong> in the UK, Final Report for WRAP.


product, especially when bioactive organic compounds were found to be present in<br />

the sludge. As is written in Hogg et al. (2008). 713<br />

587<br />

“Big retailers such as MIGROS and COOP requested that their suppliers stop<br />

using sewage sludge. Consequently, the use <strong>of</strong> sewage sludge in agriculture<br />

dropped drastically, even before any restrictive regulation was in force. The<br />

government had to find emergency solutions for the elimination <strong>of</strong> sewage<br />

sludge; a wide-ranging research project about compost was started,<br />

particularly to try to understand the degree to which fears regarding the<br />

quality <strong>of</strong> BTPs were justified. Results <strong>of</strong> two research studies demonstrated<br />

that the composts in Switzerland were <strong>of</strong> good quality, but also identified<br />

further improvements that were desirable. The research clearly demonstrated<br />

the positive effects <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> compost in preventing plant diseases in<br />

agriculture and horticulture. It appears that, rather than having too much<br />

biowaste for composting / digestion and a resultant surplus <strong>of</strong> BTPs,<br />

Switzerland now faces a shortage <strong>of</strong> supply, with energy companies turning to<br />

waste as a potential renewable energy supply, and interest in anaerobic<br />

digestion growing significantly as a result.”<br />

Livestock Pathogens<br />

A recent survey suggests that the existing approaches in those countries with most<br />

experience <strong>of</strong> composting and anaerobic digestion have generated no obvious<br />

problems in respect <strong>of</strong> livestock pathogens. The study notes: 714<br />

In conclusion, empirical evidence provides little support to the view that the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> BTPs in agriculture poses an unacceptable level <strong>of</strong> risk to farmers, their<br />

crops or their livestock, provided that systems are in place which seek to<br />

assure the quality <strong>of</strong> the BTPs. This does not mean there is zero risk<br />

associated with the use <strong>of</strong> compost. Hence, one could not suggest that the<br />

apparent absence <strong>of</strong> such a problem in the past is evidence <strong>of</strong> the<br />

impossibility <strong>of</strong> problems arising in future. It does however suggest that these<br />

risks are minimal and that the systems in place may be providing appropriate<br />

means to manage them.<br />

Furthermore, in some countries with longer experience with the use <strong>of</strong> BTPs in<br />

agriculture, the existence <strong>of</strong> quality assurance schemes has apparently led to<br />

an increase in confidence in the use <strong>of</strong> BTPs in agriculture over time,<br />

sometimes in the wake <strong>of</strong> what were, initially, distinctly unenthusiastic<br />

responses to such possible use.<br />

713 D. Hogg, D. Lister, J. Barth, E. Favoino and F. Amlinger (2009) Frameworks for Use <strong>of</strong> Compost in<br />

Agriculture in Europe, Final report for WRAP, January 2009<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/Eunomia_compost_in_agriculture_final_report.703534d2.6993.<br />

pdf .<br />

714 D. Hogg, D. Lister, J. Barth, E. Favoino and F. Amlinger (2009) Frameworks for Use <strong>of</strong> Compost in<br />

Agriculture in Europe, Final report for WRAP, January 2009<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/Eunomia_compost_in_agriculture_final_report.703534d2.6993.<br />

pdf .<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


37.0 Animal By–Products Regulations – Ireland<br />

37.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Animal by-products (ABP) include bodies <strong>of</strong> animals, parts <strong>of</strong> animals or products <strong>of</strong><br />

animal origin that are not intended for human consumption. A large amount <strong>of</strong><br />

catering waste and former foodstuffs also fall within the definition <strong>of</strong> ABP. Some<br />

animal by-products are used in animal proteins such as meat and bone meal, fats,<br />

gelatine, collagen etc. Each year around 550,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> raw ABP is produced in<br />

Ireland. 715 The use or disposal <strong>of</strong> this material has to be strictly controlled, in order to<br />

protect both public and animal health.<br />

On the 3 October 2002 the EU adopted Regulation EC 1774/2002 716, which lays<br />

down strict rules concerning the collection, transport, storage, handling, processing<br />

and use or disposal <strong>of</strong> all ABP not intended for human consumption. This regulation<br />

defines animal by-products as “entire bodies or parts <strong>of</strong> animals or products <strong>of</strong><br />

animal origin… not intended for human consumption”.<br />

The EU Animal By-Products Regulation aims to ensure that all meat and other<br />

products <strong>of</strong> animal origin, which are processed by composting, must meet specific<br />

treatment standards, to ensure sufficient pathogen removal in order that the treated<br />

compost may be safely applied to land. This Regulation permits the treatment in<br />

approved composting and biogas premises <strong>of</strong> low-risk animal by-products including<br />

catering waste. For the purpose <strong>of</strong> this review the focus is on composting. Biogas is<br />

not considered in detail as these facilities are primarily concerned with the treatment<br />

<strong>of</strong> industrial waste in Ireland at present.<br />

The Regulations classify ABP into 3 categories depending on their potential risk to<br />

animals, the public and the environment and sets out how each category must or may<br />

be disposed <strong>of</strong>.<br />

588<br />

� Category Category Category 1 1 material is very high risk material consisting <strong>of</strong> Specified Risk<br />

Material (SRM), animals suspected or confirmed <strong>of</strong> being infected with<br />

Transmissible Spongiform Encephalopathies (TSE) or Scrapie, animals killed in<br />

the context <strong>of</strong> TSE controls, carcasses <strong>of</strong> pet animals and international<br />

catering waste. Category 1 ABPs may only be disposed <strong>of</strong> by incineration, coincineration<br />

or rendering in a plant approved to handle Category 1 ABP.<br />

Category 1 catering waste from international transport may be disposed <strong>of</strong> in<br />

an approved landfill.<br />

� Category Category 2 2 material is <strong>of</strong> medium risk and includes materials such as<br />

condemned meat, fallen stock, manure or animal by-products presenting a<br />

715 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Fisheries and Food – Information Notes.<br />

716 EC No 1774/2002 <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council – Laying down health rules<br />

concerning Animal By-Products not intended for human consumption.<br />

29/09/09


589<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> contamination with other animal diseases. This includes animals, which<br />

die or are killed in the context <strong>of</strong> disease control measures on a farm.<br />

Permissible disposal routes for Category 2 material include incineration, coincineration<br />

and rendering. Provided that the material comes from wild<br />

animals, which were not killed or did not die as a result <strong>of</strong> a disease<br />

communicable to humans or animals, use <strong>of</strong> feed is allowed under<br />

authorisation to recognised species <strong>of</strong> animal. Some Category 2 ABPs can also<br />

be treated in composting or biogas plants, or can be used in oleochemical<br />

plant.<br />

� Category Category Category 33<br />

3 3 material is the lowest risk category and includes material which<br />

has previously been fit for human consumption, including catering waste, raw<br />

meat and fish, hides and skins, animal by-products derived from the<br />

processing <strong>of</strong> products and by-products which do not show signs <strong>of</strong><br />

transmissible disease. Category 3 ABPs may be disposed <strong>of</strong> by various means<br />

including at biogas plants and composting facilities.<br />

Catering waste is defined in the EU Regulation as ‘all waste food including used<br />

cooking oil originating in restaurants, catering facilities and kitchens (including central<br />

kitchens and household kitchens).<br />

Under the EU Regulation, a composting plants is defined as follows:<br />

‘A plant in which biological degradation <strong>of</strong> products <strong>of</strong> animal origin is undertaken<br />

under aerobic conditions’.<br />

Animal by-products are to be collected and transported by approved licensed hauliers<br />

and can only be stored and processed at approved licensed facilities. The <strong>Department</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Fisheries and Food (DAFF) must approve all premises involved in the<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> ABP. Pet food facilities also require a licence to operate.<br />

Annex 5 <strong>of</strong> the Regulation requires ‘complete separation <strong>of</strong> building between a<br />

processing plant and a slaughterhouse’. This is to ensure no cross contamination or<br />

substitution (voluntary or otherwise) between material intended for human<br />

consumption, material intended for animal consumption and material destined for<br />

disposal or recovery. An approved establishment must meet the required level <strong>of</strong><br />

separation.<br />

37.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The purpose <strong>of</strong> the legislation is to safeguard humans and animal health by providing<br />

controls for the safe use and disposal <strong>of</strong> animal by-products hence avoiding<br />

contamination <strong>of</strong> the food chain.<br />

The scientific basis for the ABP Legislation is to prevent the risk <strong>of</strong> disease, as<br />

epidemiological studies carried out on Bovine Spongiform Encephalopathy BSE, the<br />

dioxin scare, animal diseases such as Foot and Mouth Disease and Classical Swine<br />

Fever have all identified animal-by products as the source. It is believed that the<br />

outbreaks in the UK in recent years <strong>of</strong> both foot-and-mouth and swine fever were<br />

caused by contaminated catering waste and therefore Ireland needs to ensure that all<br />

ABP are disposed <strong>of</strong> properly.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


37.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

Regulation EC 1774/2002 was transposed into Irish Law on May 1 2003 by the<br />

Animal By-Product Regulations 2003 (S.I. No. 248 <strong>of</strong> 2003) 717 and by the Animal By-<br />

Products (Amendment) Regulations 2005 (S.I. 707 <strong>of</strong> 2005) 718 . The legislation<br />

permitted Member States to introduce national legislation to complement and<br />

enforce the EU rules. EU Regulation No. 208/2006 719 provides for composting plants<br />

to operate to other standards subject to appropriate validation and a full risk<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> the standards. Ireland introduced the following legislation to<br />

complement the EU rules:<br />

590<br />

� S.I. No. 612 (Transmissible Spongiform Encephalopathies and Animal By-<br />

Products) Regulations 2006 implements EU Regulation No. 181 <strong>of</strong> 2006; and<br />

� S. I. No. 615 (Diseases <strong>of</strong> Animals Act 1966) (Transmissible Spongiform<br />

Encephalopathies) (Fertilisers and Soil Improvers) Order 2006 applies stricter<br />

national rules for organic fertilisers and soil improvers under EU Regulation<br />

No. 181 <strong>of</strong> 2006.<br />

Following a consultation process, these statutory instruments were subsequently<br />

amended in 2008 to the following:<br />

� S.I. No. 252 <strong>of</strong> 2008 (European Communities (Transmissible Spongiform<br />

Encephalopathies and Animal By-Products) Regulations 2008; and<br />

� S.I. No. 253 <strong>of</strong> 2008 (Diseases <strong>of</strong> Animals Act 1966 (Transmissible<br />

Spongiform Encephalopathies) (Fertilisers and Soil improvers) Order 2008.<br />

In addition milk and dairy products can be fed to animals, subject to the restrictions<br />

set out in EU Regulation 79/2005 720 . The Swill Order (S.I. 597/2001) 721 bans the<br />

feeding to farm animals <strong>of</strong> ‘any broken or waste foodstuff (including table, catering or<br />

kitchen refuse, scraps or waste)’. However, the order makes an exception for cereal<br />

grains, edible material <strong>of</strong> plant or vegetable origin, bread and dough (including<br />

biscuits) and chocolate that has not been in contact with an animal or animal<br />

product. On January 20 2009, S.I. No. 12 <strong>of</strong> 2009 722 amended Statutory Instrument<br />

No. 597/2001 permitting the collection, assembly, processing and storage <strong>of</strong> swill at<br />

approved composting plants.<br />

717 S.I. No. 248 <strong>of</strong> 2003, Animal By-Product Regulations 2003.<br />

718 S.I. No. 707 <strong>of</strong> 2005, Animal By-Products (Amendment) Regulations 2005.<br />

719 EC No.208/2006 <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council as regards processing standards<br />

for biogas and composting plants and requirements for manure.<br />

720 EC No. 79 <strong>of</strong> 2005 <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council implementing Regulation (EC)<br />

No 1774/2002 <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament and <strong>of</strong> the Council as regards the use <strong>of</strong> milk, milk-based<br />

products and milk-derived products, defined as Category 3 material in that Regulation.<br />

721 S.I. No. 597 <strong>of</strong> 2001. Diseases <strong>of</strong> Animals Act, 1966 (Prohibition on the Use <strong>of</strong> Swill) Order, 2001.<br />

722 S.I. No. 12 <strong>of</strong> 2009 Diseases <strong>of</strong> Animals Act, 1966 (Prohibition on the Use <strong>of</strong> Swill) (Amendment)<br />

Order 2009.<br />

29/09/09


37.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Implementation <strong>of</strong> ABP Regulations is handled by a number <strong>of</strong> bodies. The<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture Fisheries and Food (DAFF) is the central competent<br />

authority with its primary role as regulator. All premises involved in the composting<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> animal by-products must be approved by DAFF. Such approval is<br />

additional to any planning or other licensing approval that may be required. DAFF<br />

support the development <strong>of</strong> a quality compost industry and focus specifically on the<br />

safe use <strong>of</strong> ABP as a compost feedstock. DAFF’s main aim is to promote an<br />

environment friendly and sustainable process. DAFF also provide veterinary<br />

inspectors to carry out monthly, quarterly or annual inspections on facilities<br />

depending on the terms <strong>of</strong> the licence or in the instance <strong>of</strong> a complaint. The Local<br />

Authority Veterinary Service is responsible for ABP issues in smaller local abattoirs;<br />

and the Health Service Executive, deals with retail outlets handling ABP, such as<br />

butchers 723.<br />

37.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

Compost plants treating Category 3 animal by-products and catering waste must meet<br />

certain time/temperature treatment standards as set out in Annex VI <strong>of</strong> EU Regulation<br />

1774/2002. The EU standard for treatment <strong>of</strong> animal by-products (including milk and<br />

manure) is treatment at 70°C for 1 hour with a maximum particle size <strong>of</strong> 12mm.<br />

Catering waste (with or without manure and/or digestive tract content) may be<br />

treated to the Irish National Standard: 60°C for 48 hours (twice) with a maximum<br />

particle size <strong>of</strong> 400mm. This is allowable owing to the exemption afforded to catering<br />

waste which is not <strong>of</strong> international origin under Article 6 <strong>of</strong> the EU ABP Regulations.<br />

SI 253/2008 permits that the spreading <strong>of</strong> organic fertiliser/soil improvers derived<br />

from the list <strong>of</strong> feedstocks given below is permissible provided farmed animals do not<br />

have access to the land concerned for at least 21 days following application. The 21<br />

day period is extended to 60 days in the case <strong>of</strong> pigs because <strong>of</strong> their susceptibility to<br />

disease. The restriction applies mainly but not exclusively to pastureland. In addition,<br />

ensiled crop or hay can also be made after 21 days <strong>of</strong> landspreading compost on that<br />

land.<br />

The permissible feedstocks are as follows:<br />

591<br />

� Catering waste as defined in Article 6 1 (l), EU Regulation 1774/2002;<br />

� Former foodstuffs as defined in Article 6 1 (f), EU Regulation 1774/2002,<br />

including raw materials;<br />

� Manure and digestive tract content;<br />

� Raw milk from animals not showing signs <strong>of</strong> any communicable disease as<br />

defined in Article 6 1 (g), EU Regulation 1774/2002;<br />

723 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Fisheries and Food – Frequently Asked Questions.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


592<br />

� Fresh by-products from fish as defined in Article 6 1 (i), EU Regulation<br />

1774/2002;<br />

� Fish or other sea animals caught in the open sea for the purpose <strong>of</strong> fishmeal<br />

production as defined in Article 6 1 (h), EU Regulation 1774/2002 ;<br />

� Shells, hatchery by-products and cracked egg products from animals not<br />

showing signs <strong>of</strong> any communicable disease, as defined in Article 6 1 (j), EU<br />

Regulation 1774/2002; and<br />

� Feathers.<br />

37.5.1 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

There are no ex post evaluation studies available. The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture,<br />

Food and Fisheries was contacted in relation to studies carried out on the progress <strong>of</strong><br />

the ABP Regulations in preventing the risk <strong>of</strong> disease and epidemiological outbreaks.<br />

They are unaware <strong>of</strong> any such evaluation studies.<br />

� Cré – Composting Association <strong>of</strong> Ireland Teo, Irish Bioenergy Association, Irish<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Association, October 2007 - Submission to the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Fisheries and Food on ABP Regulations;<br />

� Cré – Composting Association <strong>of</strong> Ireland Teo, November 2008 - Submission to<br />

the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Fisheries and Food on Draft ABP Compost<br />

Guidance Document;<br />

� Cré – Composting Association <strong>of</strong> Ireland Teo, February 2009 - Submission to<br />

Eunomia on <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Policies for Composting/Digestion in relation to the<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> in Ireland;<br />

� EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007; and<br />

� EPA Report published in 2002 “Assessment and Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Outlets <strong>of</strong><br />

Compost Produced From Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>. 724 ” This document provides a<br />

national strategy to develop adequate and reliable compost market and nonmarket<br />

outlets for the putrescible fraction <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste.<br />

37.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

Under the National Strategy on Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong>, the Government has<br />

established targets to meet for the recycling or composting <strong>of</strong> household waste for<br />

Ireland. By 2010, 25% <strong>of</strong> all household waste must be recycled or composted. Under<br />

the EU Landfill Directive, Ireland also has to meet targets for the reduction <strong>of</strong><br />

biodegradable municipal waste sent for landfill. By 2010 the amount <strong>of</strong><br />

biodegradable municipal waste sent for landfill must be reduced to 25% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

amount produced in 1995. The development <strong>of</strong> composting and biogas plants will be<br />

necessary for achieving these targets.<br />

724 Paul van der Werf, Caitríona Carter, Gene Browne, Mac Dara Hosty (2002) Assessment and<br />

Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Outlets <strong>of</strong> Compost Produced From Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>, Report to the EPA.<br />

29/09/09


37.6.1 Environmental Benefits - Prevention<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> prevention falls under the definition <strong>of</strong> minimising the quantity and<br />

hazardousness <strong>of</strong> waste generated. The ABP Regulations ultimately prevent the risk<br />

<strong>of</strong> disease caused by contaminated ABP and catering waste by introducing controls<br />

for the safe use and disposal <strong>of</strong> animal by-products hence avoiding contamination <strong>of</strong><br />

the food chain.<br />

37.6.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

The manner <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> the ABP Regulations, although not completely a<br />

‘recycling policy’, will determine the costs <strong>of</strong> meeting, and the ease <strong>of</strong> meeting,<br />

specific targets for ensuring biodegradable waste is not landfilled. It has been<br />

commented elsewhere in the UK for example) that it is anomalous that the Directive<br />

does not address the issue <strong>of</strong> potential transmission <strong>of</strong> livestock diseases at landfills.<br />

Consequently, few rules apply to landfilling ABP, but rules apply to composting and<br />

biogas plants.<br />

Studies elsewhere suggest that, in particular where biogas plants are used, the<br />

environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling biodegradable waste are positive relative to<br />

residual waste treatment / disposal. Hence, a rational and proportionate<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the ABPR has the potential to a) enhance the sustainability <strong>of</strong><br />

management <strong>of</strong> biodegradable wastes whilst b) giving confidence to end-users <strong>of</strong><br />

compost that the end product is adequately hygienised. On the other hand, an<br />

onerous and disproportionate approach would risk undermining the potential benefits<br />

to be derived (not least in agriculture itself).<br />

37.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Food and Fisheries incurred a number <strong>of</strong> costs in<br />

relation to the administering <strong>of</strong> the policy. DAFF were contacted in relation to<br />

implementation costs and were unable to provide information on this. Facility<br />

operators do not pay fees in relation to the regulations. They do, however, have to<br />

ensure their facility is operated in line with DAFF requirements (see below).<br />

37.8 Response from Public and Industry<br />

The outbreak <strong>of</strong> foot-and-mouth disease in the country in 2001 led to the introduction<br />

<strong>of</strong> rigorous legislation in Ireland, which greatly restricted the siting, reception, and<br />

processing <strong>of</strong> animal by-products and the beneficial uses permissible for the treated<br />

products. To provide clarity on the veterinary requirements, the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

Agriculture and Food issued draft information notes Conditions for Approval and<br />

Operation <strong>of</strong> Composting Plants Treating Animal By-Products in Ireland and Guidance<br />

for Applicants Wishing to Treat Animal By-Products in Composting and Biogas Plants<br />

in Ireland.<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> submissions were received from industry, citing concern in relation to the<br />

legislation. Issues in relation to the requirements <strong>of</strong> double fencing, compost end-use<br />

labelling, compost end-use recording to horticulture, hygiene and validation were<br />

highlighted in the submissions. The latest draft <strong>of</strong> the conditions has taken these<br />

593<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


concerns into consideration allowing less stringent and more workable regulations for<br />

composting.<br />

The ABP Regulations establish a quality assurance scheme for the production <strong>of</strong><br />

compost which should reassure end users <strong>of</strong> the hygienic nature <strong>of</strong> the end product.<br />

This ought to help stimulate demand and hence instil a confidence amongst potential<br />

users and the public.<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> food businesses have been affected by the implementation <strong>of</strong> the policy.<br />

These include food manufacturers, butchers, fishmongers, bakers, retailers, caterers<br />

and distributors. <strong>Waste</strong> from all <strong>of</strong> these premises must be disposed <strong>of</strong> in accordance<br />

with the Regulations.<br />

Existing research on the potential outlets for compost derived from biodegradable<br />

waste, which suggested outlets for 447,750 tonnes <strong>of</strong> compost per annum, may be<br />

considered quite optimistic. 725 Animal by-products legislation imposes some<br />

landspreading restrictions on compost derived from specific materials. The advent <strong>of</strong><br />

the Nitrates Directive may also mean that farmers may be reluctant to accept<br />

nutrients from <strong>of</strong>f-farm sources. Regulations on the nutrient availability and spreading<br />

<strong>of</strong> sludge will restrict the economic viability <strong>of</strong> landspreading, and more generally<br />

there is public opposition to landspreading <strong>of</strong> treated waste. 726<br />

Development <strong>of</strong> markets for the recovered biodegradable municipal waste is central<br />

to the success <strong>of</strong> the National Strategy on Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong>. A Market<br />

Development Group <strong>of</strong> key stakeholders was established in 2004, under the<br />

guidance <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Department</strong>, with the objective <strong>of</strong> driving forward the development <strong>of</strong><br />

existing markets for recyclables and identifying new applications and markets for<br />

recyclables and secondary recycled products 727 . Given a high-quality sourceseparated<br />

feedstock, it is important to ensure that the composting process will result<br />

in compost that has similar qualities to existing organic amendments, as well as the<br />

ability to develop unique and potentially marketable attributes. Reasonable process<br />

management requirements, monitoring and end-product requirements should be<br />

developed. It may be useful to develop a guide to assist producers <strong>of</strong> compost in<br />

making a high-quality product. 728<br />

37.9 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The Regulations will clearly affect, directly, the operation <strong>of</strong> composting and biogas<br />

facilities. The intention <strong>of</strong> the Regulations is to ensure that techniques render the<br />

outputs unproblematic when they are spread on land.<br />

725 Paul van der Werf, Caitríona Carter, Gene Browne, Mac Dara Hosty (2002) Assessment and<br />

Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Outlets <strong>of</strong> Compost Produced From Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>, Report to the EPA.<br />

726 EPA (2008) Hitting the Targets for Biodegradable Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>: Ten Options for Change,<br />

Wexford: EPA, January 2008.<br />

727 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government, July 2008 - Circular WPPR 17/08.<br />

728 Paul van der Werf, Caitríona Carter, Gene Browne, Mac Dara Hosty (2002) Assessment and<br />

Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Outlets <strong>of</strong> Compost Produced From Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>, Report to the EPA.<br />

594<br />

29/09/09


For proposed new composting facilities wishing to process animal by-products<br />

including catering waste, the approval process is separated into two stages. The first<br />

stage is a notification <strong>of</strong> intention to build a facility. The second stage is a formal<br />

application for approval when the facility is built. The first stage application provides<br />

information on the location, plant layout and processing technology/parameters, as<br />

well as intended feedstock and end use <strong>of</strong> compost/digestate. The <strong>Department</strong>’s<br />

Veterinary Inspectors advise <strong>of</strong> any technical change in relation to processing<br />

technology and parameters ensuring that plant design and processing procedures are<br />

in accordance with the regulations, and to help identify and correct potential<br />

problems prior to capital expenditure. The DAFF also encourage alternative<br />

commercially viable uses <strong>of</strong> such ABP products in Ireland which are consistent with<br />

the Regulations.<br />

In June 2006, the Minister for Agriculture, Fisheries and Food introduced a Scheme <strong>of</strong><br />

Investment Aid for Demonstration On-Farm <strong>Waste</strong> Processing Facilities. This scheme<br />

provided grant-aid for up to 10 projects throughout the State for the introduction or<br />

development <strong>of</strong> on-farm waste processing facilities such as anaerobic/aerobic<br />

digestion and fluidised bed combustion systems. The criteria for selection <strong>of</strong> projects<br />

included the potential <strong>of</strong> the proposed project for the creation <strong>of</strong> a renewable energy<br />

source.<br />

37.10 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

In principle, the approach shifts additional costs on to the waste management sector<br />

in favour <strong>of</strong> reducing risk for the agricultural sector. Within the waste management<br />

sector, to the extent that costs are increased for the management <strong>of</strong> biowaste<br />

through composting and digestion, the policy shift matters slightly in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

disposal and residual waste treatment.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> management companies say that it is not financially viable for them to collect<br />

catering waste as a single waste stream. There is significant cost associated with this<br />

to ensure that the waste is not contaminated with feedstocks that do not form part <strong>of</strong><br />

the permissible feedstocks list. The cause <strong>of</strong> this problem is regulatory uncertainty<br />

that affects investment decisions, not solely economics. There are a few waste<br />

management companies now collecting household biodegradable waste as a<br />

separate waste stream.<br />

37.11 Complementary Policies<br />

Circular (WPPR 17/08) was issued on the implementation <strong>of</strong> Segregated ‘Brown Bin’<br />

Collection for Biowaste and Home Composting. This Circular was issued in the wake<br />

<strong>of</strong> a growing concern regarding Ireland’s ability to meet the targets for reducing the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste sent to landfill as set out in the EU Landfill Directive.<br />

The Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government is currently working<br />

on a Statutory Instrument (SI) for Commercial Organic <strong>Waste</strong> to be Segregated. The<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> the SI is to ensure that, where in the commercial sector a significant source <strong>of</strong><br />

organic waste arises, it will be segregated at source and presented for collection. This<br />

sourced separated material is then suitable for downstream processing in approved<br />

composting and anaerobic digestion facilities. This will give security <strong>of</strong> feedstock<br />

supply to existing facilities and encourage new facilities to be built. The SI is not<br />

595<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


extended to householders, but is intended to catch all other non-household sources<br />

<strong>of</strong> significant quantities <strong>of</strong> the organic fraction <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste. The<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> this statutory instrument would rapidly divert large volumes <strong>of</strong><br />

biodegradable waste from landfill and is easily achievable in the commercial sector.<br />

This legislation will be available for comment via a consultative group.<br />

In addition, the work <strong>of</strong> the Market Development Group, and the development <strong>of</strong><br />

standards will assist in making compost more acceptable to end-users.<br />

37.12 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

There has been no systematic evaluation <strong>of</strong> the effect on costs <strong>of</strong> the Regulations in<br />

their final form. Cré commented on the Draft regulations and highlighted some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

potential cost implications <strong>of</strong> the Regulations in Draft form. The approach does have<br />

the effect <strong>of</strong> increasing costs in line with what one might call a precautionary<br />

approach. It is not, here, the intention to internalise externalities, rather it is the<br />

intention to prevent the incidence <strong>of</strong> new outbreaks <strong>of</strong> animal pathogens.<br />

Biological treatment facilities can contribute significantly to diverting material from<br />

landfill and achieving Ireland’s recycling targets. Ireland remains the most expensive<br />

<strong>of</strong> the benchmark countries for biological waste treatment gate fees and, following<br />

increases in gate fees from €80 per tonne in 2005 to €90 in 2006, is now<br />

significantly above the benchmark <strong>of</strong> the other countries in terms <strong>of</strong> prices. 729 The<br />

higher gate fee for biological treatment in Ireland can in part be attributed to the<br />

relatively small scale and limited number <strong>of</strong> facilities in operation, leading to less<br />

competition, as well as relatively restrictive legislation. Currently there are seven<br />

approved ABP facilities in Ireland. The supply <strong>of</strong> these facilities is slow due to<br />

regulatory uncertainty, and where demand exists, arguably, prices can be set high<br />

owing to an absence <strong>of</strong> competition.<br />

37.13 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Under the relevant ABP legislation the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture, Food and Fisheries<br />

veterinary inspectorate is empowered to take suitable action to protect public and<br />

animal health at approved plants where the operators <strong>of</strong> plants fail to comply with the<br />

requirements <strong>of</strong> the legislation. Each composting plant must have its own laboratory<br />

or make use <strong>of</strong> an external laboratory. The laboratory must be equipped to carry out<br />

the necessary analyses and approved by the competent authority. Sampling must be<br />

done in accordance with the approval as issued to a plant. In cases where noncompliance<br />

occurs where samples result in a serious hygiene risk the following<br />

applies:<br />

596<br />

• The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Food must be notified immediately<br />

• The operator <strong>of</strong> the plant must establish the cause <strong>of</strong> the failure.<br />

729 Forfás (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Benchmarking Analysis and <strong>Policy</strong> Priorities, May 2008.<br />

29/09/09


597<br />

• The contaminated batch and any in-contact material must be re-processed or<br />

disposed <strong>of</strong> under the supervision <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Food.<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> facilities where the only animal by-product being processed is<br />

catering waste, contaminated batches may be sent directly for landfill or<br />

recycled through the plant. For facilities using Category 3 animal by-products,<br />

material may either be recycled through the plant or sent for processing in an<br />

approved Category 3 processing plant.<br />

• No material suspected <strong>of</strong> being contaminated must be removed from the plant<br />

without the prior approval <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Food.<br />

• The frequency <strong>of</strong> sampling and testing will be increased in line with the<br />

recommendations in place at the time<br />

• Records relating to the contaminated material must be investigated<br />

• Appropriate decontamination and cleaning procedures must be followed.<br />

Failure to comply with the conditions <strong>of</strong> the notice may result in the closure <strong>of</strong> the<br />

plant and possible prosecution.<br />

37.14 Lessons Learned<br />

The Regulations have been changed over time, shifting to what one might call a more<br />

proportionate approach to final implementation.<br />

The EPA is responsible for collecting data through the National <strong>Waste</strong> Report project.<br />

The EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007 highlighted that less than 9% <strong>of</strong> organic wastes<br />

were recovered in 2007. This is disappointing considering the looming landfill<br />

diversion targets for biodegradable municipal waste and the fact that the organics<br />

fraction is where attention must be focused. 730<br />

It was noted in the National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2006 that the separate collection and<br />

diversion from landfill (by recycling or other means) <strong>of</strong> organic waste needs to be<br />

accelerated. Stringent legislation including strict validation and hygiene requirements<br />

has limited the number <strong>of</strong> private sector investments. Over time however this<br />

legislation has become more workable and the ABP Regulations have occasioned a<br />

stronger partnership approach. This has been successful, yet arguably, it should have<br />

been adopted from the outset.<br />

730 EPA, National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


38.0 Policies For Dealing With Junk Mail<br />

38.1 Description<br />

Junk mail can be defined as direct mail (both to potential and existing customers),<br />

door to door materials, inserts included with magazines and newspapers, and free<br />

newspapers. Some <strong>of</strong> these materials are not delivered to householders but picked<br />

up by potential customers “on the go” (flyers and free newspapers).<br />

The size <strong>of</strong> the junk mail waste streams has been estimated, in the UK for example,<br />

at 3-5% <strong>of</strong> household arisings, 731 whilst according to the French environment ministry<br />

the average French household receives 40kg <strong>of</strong> unsolicited printed materials each<br />

year.<br />

38.2 Possible Measures to be Taken<br />

There are various measures that could be taken to reduce these waste streams,<br />

which range from an opt-out, application <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility to an outright ban.<br />

An opt-out – already available in the form <strong>of</strong> the mailing preference service – requires<br />

action by individual householders, is relatively cumbersome and only covers some<br />

categories <strong>of</strong> junk mail. A ban may be seen as restricting the right to advertise<br />

products, and so also is only applicable to certain defined categories <strong>of</strong> materials. A<br />

number <strong>of</strong> measures that have been considered are listed in Table 38-1, which is<br />

taken from a 2007 waste prevention report. 732<br />

Whilst not all <strong>of</strong> these might be directly construed as ‘policies’, such as campaigns for<br />

tighter targeting <strong>of</strong> recipients, they can complement policies which set the economic<br />

climate for prevention, or they might be initiatives which are pursued with additional<br />

vigour as a consequence <strong>of</strong> some form <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility.<br />

731 National Resource & <strong>Waste</strong> Forum (2004) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Toolkit, Part C. Marketing<br />

Behaviour Change.<br />

732 Eunomia, The Environment Council, Oko Institut, TNO and Atlantic Consulting (2007) Household<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention: <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report for Defra, April 2007.<br />

598<br />

29/09/09


Table 38-1: Junk Mail Policies<br />

Name Name<br />

Description Description<br />

Typ Type Typ<br />

Exists Exists Exists in<br />

in<br />

Activist<br />

campaign<br />

599<br />

Pressure on mailers or on listproviders<br />

to limit junk mail<br />

Ban, specific Prohibition on delivering<br />

unstamped or unfranked items to<br />

letter boxes<br />

Opt-out A service that allows consumers<br />

to have their names and home<br />

addresses removed from or<br />

added to mailing lists used by<br />

mailers<br />

Postage<br />

increase (on<br />

bulk mail)<br />

Levy (with<br />

producer<br />

responsibility)<br />

Higher tariffs for bulk mailing, in<br />

order to discourage junk mail<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> levy on direct mail / free<br />

newspapers. This would have<br />

similar impact to postage<br />

increases but would use a<br />

different legislative mechanism.<br />

Suppression Removal <strong>of</strong> records from a<br />

mailing file or database that are<br />

no longer accurate or current, or<br />

records <strong>of</strong> people who have opted<br />

out.<br />

Notification <strong>of</strong><br />

MPS on mail<br />

Legislative<br />

reinforcement<br />

<strong>of</strong> ‘No Junk<br />

Mail’ stickers<br />

All junk mail could be required to<br />

have details <strong>of</strong> MPS and the<br />

householders rights printed in the<br />

material (similar to food labelling).<br />

A requirement to encourage<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> material could also be<br />

included.<br />

Legal obligation on distributors <strong>of</strong><br />

junk mail to not put items in<br />

boxes displaying ‘No Junk Mail’<br />

stickers. This requires a firm<br />

definition <strong>of</strong> junk mail and good<br />

enforcement structures.<br />

Licensing Distributors <strong>of</strong> junk mail are<br />

licensed to ensure they abide by<br />

industry codes. Businesses using<br />

unlicensed distributors could be<br />

liable for fines.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Executive or<br />

ministerial decision<br />

Legislation or<br />

administrative rule<br />

Voluntary<br />

agreement or<br />

mandatory<br />

legislation<br />

Numerous regions in<br />

the UK and other<br />

countries<br />

USA<br />

Voluntary opt-outs<br />

available in the UK,<br />

Germany, other EU<br />

countries and the<br />

USA.<br />

Legislation No postage increases<br />

to limit junk mail are<br />

known.<br />

Legislation<br />

Voluntary<br />

agreement or<br />

legislation<br />

Legislation<br />

Voluntary agreement<br />

in the UK<br />

Legislation Australia (legislation<br />

and schemes vary by<br />

state)<br />

Legislation<br />

Brussels


38.3 Examples<br />

38.3.1 French Unwanted Mail Decree<br />

The French government took decisive action in 2006 in the form <strong>of</strong> an extended<br />

producer responsibility scheme to attempt to reduce the volume <strong>of</strong> junk mail sent to<br />

households each year. Distributors <strong>of</strong> junk mail have to pay for the recycling <strong>of</strong> the<br />

resultant waste under a decree agreed by the council <strong>of</strong> ministers. This sector has<br />

been informed that if it fails to comply with the decree, the government will introduce<br />

a tax on junk mail.<br />

The decree states that the participants can either pay into a fund that will be used to<br />

pay for recycling by local authorities or they can pay for advertising to encourage<br />

consumers to recycle. Payment levels were set in late 2006 after meetings between<br />

the government and interested parties.<br />

38.3.2 Voluntary Agreements<br />

The UK has had a voluntary agreement between DEFRA and the Direct Mail<br />

Association since 2003, aimed at increasing recycling rates. They increased from<br />

13% in 2003 to 28% in 2005, although this should be seen in context <strong>of</strong> a general<br />

increase in recycling levels. The amount <strong>of</strong> addressed direct mail has fallen by around<br />

5% since 2003, according to DEFRA.<br />

The mailing preference service (MPS) is a significant part <strong>of</strong> the industry’s response to<br />

concerns and allows householders to register to opt out <strong>of</strong> receiving direct mail. One<br />

way in which a policy could be designed to increase the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the service<br />

would be to mandate the promotion <strong>of</strong> it on direct mail items.<br />

38.3.3 Enforcing the ‘No Junk Mail’ Sticker<br />

In Australia, the opt out has been strengthened by legislative reinforcement: it is<br />

legally binding to respect the no junk mail sticker on householders’ doors. The<br />

Distribution Standards Board maintains a database <strong>of</strong> all known addresses that carry<br />

a restrictive sign on the letterbox.<br />

38.3.4 Postage Levy<br />

An increase in the cost <strong>of</strong> postage, or a waste level on bulk mailings would increase<br />

the cost <strong>of</strong> direct mailings, with the aim <strong>of</strong> increasing the targeting, and the decrease<br />

in waste. There may be a question mark over the price elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand, and this<br />

policy would only impact mailed items, rather than hand delivered. There do not<br />

appear to be any examples <strong>of</strong> this policy having been implemented.<br />

38.3.5 Extended Producer Responsibility<br />

Extended producer responsibility would oblige the direct mail industry to cover the<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> separate collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> junk mail. The revenue from such a policy<br />

would be redistributed to local authorities to support the costs <strong>of</strong> junk mail. Making<br />

the real cost <strong>of</strong> these marketing materials fall on those responsible would incentivise<br />

600<br />

29/09/09


them to increase efforts at suppression (keeping mailing lists up to date), and<br />

targeting.<br />

The UK’s current DMA voluntary agreement is titled a producer responsibility scheme<br />

and refers to the pledge by the Association to 733 :<br />

601<br />

“Work with local authorities to promote kerbside collections <strong>of</strong> paper to be<br />

recycled, and to make sure the collections have the capacity to meet recycling<br />

targets”<br />

This pledge has translated into the Association promoting the mail preference service<br />

with local authorities. However, no financial help is built into the agreement. This does<br />

not correspond with the OECD’s definition <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility 734:<br />

“OECD defines EPR as an environmental policy approach in which a<br />

producer’s responsibility for a product is extended to the post-consumer stage<br />

<strong>of</strong> a product’s life cycle. An EPR policy is characterised by: (1) the shifting <strong>of</strong><br />

responsibility (physically and/or economically; fully or partially) upstream<br />

toward the producer and away from municipalities; and (2) the provision <strong>of</strong><br />

incentives to producers to take into account environmental considerations<br />

when designing their products.”<br />

The voluntary approach is weakened by virtue <strong>of</strong> the absence <strong>of</strong> any incentives for<br />

producers other than those which already exist as a consequence <strong>of</strong> ongoing<br />

activities.<br />

38.4 Possible Impacts<br />

A report written for Defra in the UK estimated the waste prevention impacts <strong>of</strong> the<br />

measures and Table 38-2 shows the resulting changes in percentage <strong>of</strong> total direct<br />

mail annual tonnage prevented: 735<br />

733 Section on the Defra website entitled Producer Responsibility Voluntary Agreements,<br />

http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/waste/producer/voluntary/index.htm<br />

734 Taken from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Environment Directorate<br />

website , http://www.oecd.org/document/19/0,3343,en_2649_34281_35158227_1_1_1_1,00.html<br />

735 D. Hogg et al (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Report for<br />

DEFRA, April 2007.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 38-2: Direct Mail Policies and Their Estimated Impact<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> Description<br />

Existing Suppression<br />

Enhanced Opt-outs<br />

Postage Levy<br />

Producer Responsibility<br />

Levy<br />

Enforcement <strong>of</strong> no junk<br />

mail stickers<br />

602<br />

29/09/09<br />

Existing Direct Mail<br />

Agreement<br />

Promotion <strong>of</strong> Mailing<br />

Preference Service<br />

Increase in costs <strong>of</strong><br />

direct mail-related<br />

post (by 10% <strong>of</strong> price)<br />

Targets for recycling<br />

supported by cost<br />

recovery from users <strong>of</strong><br />

direct mail<br />

Legal support for<br />

rejection <strong>of</strong> junk mail<br />

Impact on Direct<br />

Mail<br />

(%)<br />

Impact on Free<br />

Newspapers etc.<br />

(%)<br />

2 n/a<br />

6 - 9 n/a<br />

4 - 8 n/a<br />

1 - 9 Potentially similar<br />

15 15<br />

The percentages sometimes have a wide range as they take into account not only the<br />

range <strong>of</strong> estimates <strong>of</strong> the size <strong>of</strong> the direct mail sector in terms <strong>of</strong> tonnage, but also<br />

estimates <strong>of</strong> the elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand for it. It is worth noting that only two policies –<br />

producer responsibility and enforceable no junk mail stickers - have an impact on<br />

non-mailed items such as free newspapers.<br />

Measures to limit the number <strong>of</strong> free flyers and newspapers could also have an<br />

impact on the litter situation. Indeed, it was litter legislation that was enacted in<br />

Australia to outlaw junk mail delivered to houses with a “no junk mail” sticker. Part <strong>of</strong><br />

any financial support to local authorities given as a part <strong>of</strong> a producer responsibility<br />

scheme could be used to fund street cleansing operations to tackle the issue <strong>of</strong><br />

discarded flyers and newspapers.<br />

The percentages <strong>of</strong> waste prevention were translated into tonnages and cost savings<br />

as seen in Table 38-3. 736 Postage levy is excluded as it would be difficult to ensure<br />

that only direct mail was affected by it.<br />

736 Original amounts were in UK Sterling: these have been converted at a rate <strong>of</strong> 1.25 Euros to the<br />

Pound.


Table 38-3: Cost Savings from Junk Mail Policies<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> Impact (tones)<br />

603<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Avoided Collection<br />

and Disposal<br />

Cost Savings<br />

Low High Low High Low High<br />

Existing Suppression 7,860 13,100 €123 €150 €962,850 €1,965,000<br />

Enhanced Opt-outs 36,500 36,500 €123 €150 €4,471,250 €5,475,000<br />

Postage Levy 15,000 50,000 €123 €150 €1,837,500 €7,500,000<br />

Producer Responsibility Levy 6,400 35,400 €123 €150 €784,000 €5,310,000<br />

Enforcement <strong>of</strong> junk mail stickers 112,500 187,500 €123 €150 €13,781,250 €28,125,000<br />

Total Total New New New Policies Policies (excl (excl postage postage levy) levy)<br />

€19,036,500 €38,910,000<br />

38.5 Conclusions<br />

Junk mail is a significant though not massive part <strong>of</strong> the waste stream at 3-5% <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste arisings. The industry in Ireland was recently estimated by the<br />

chairperson <strong>of</strong> the Irish Direct Mail Association to account for 3% <strong>of</strong> GDP. 737<br />

The waste stream concerned is particularly amenable to being addressed through<br />

producer responsibility, which would incentivise the industry to target customers more<br />

accurately to reduce the costs <strong>of</strong> recycling/disposal, and would be expected to visit<br />

the costs <strong>of</strong> managing the direct marketing (and free newspaper) stream through<br />

seeking to ensure that the costs <strong>of</strong> managing the associated wastes were visited<br />

upon producers. Indeed, in this way, households would be expected to be faced with<br />

lower charges for their waste collection services (at the margin).<br />

A policy to respect the preference <strong>of</strong> householders would result in a virtuous cycle <strong>of</strong><br />

behaviour: householders would be more inclined to express their preference if they<br />

were confident that it would be respected, and direct mailers would gradually change<br />

their volumes (or methods) to reflect the number <strong>of</strong> households opting out. To the<br />

extent that this might reduce the nuisance experienced by householders and avoid<br />

their resulting alienation, there may be a collateral (difficult to quantify) external<br />

benefit.<br />

The measures such as those outlined can also be used as a lever to encourage the<br />

industry to do things that are not amenable to direct policy intervention, such as<br />

enhanced mail targeting.<br />

737 Taken from the IDMA website: http://www.directbrand.ie/idma/newsdetails.aspx


CONSTRUCTION AND DEMOLITION WASTE<br />

604<br />

29/09/09


39.0 <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Irish <strong>Policy</strong>, Construction &<br />

Demolition <strong>Waste</strong><br />

39.1 Background:<br />

The National <strong>Waste</strong> Database defines C&D <strong>Waste</strong> as ‘all waste that arises from<br />

construction, renovation and demolition activities and all waste mentioned in Chapter<br />

17 <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>Waste</strong> Catalogue (EMC). The C&D wastes listed in Chapter 17 <strong>of</strong><br />

the catalogue include 44 waste types, 16 <strong>of</strong> which have been classified as hazardous<br />

wastes. The treatment, collection, transfer and disposal <strong>of</strong> hazardous material are<br />

subject to additional regulatory controls under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Hazardous<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>) Regulations 1998.<br />

Construction and Demolition (C&D) waste is a very significant component <strong>of</strong> the<br />

overall waste stream in Ireland, particularly with the high levels <strong>of</strong> building and<br />

development in recent years.<br />

C&D waste management in Ireland has historically been characterised by an overreliance<br />

on landfill as a disposal route.<br />

According to the 2007 National <strong>Waste</strong> Report published by the EPA, Construction and<br />

Demolition waste generation increased by 5.8% since 2006 to an all-time high <strong>of</strong><br />

almost 18 million tonnes, including approximately 4 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste other<br />

than soil and stones. The data on this huge and important waste stream is sparse<br />

and reported recycling rates are down on previous years.<br />

New momentum is required if the construction industry is to demonstrate its progress<br />

towards the targets and objectives set out in national policy and in the industry’s own<br />

voluntary initiative (discussed below) for the improved management <strong>of</strong> C&D waste.<br />

The downturn in the Irish construction industry experienced from late 2007 onwards<br />

has no doubt influenced the quantities <strong>of</strong> C&D waste generated in 2008 and 2009.<br />

This downturn coupled with the recent financial crisis experienced worldwide will<br />

most likely impose a downward pressure on the quantities <strong>of</strong> C&D waste generated in<br />

the short to medium term. It is probable that a downward trend in C&D quantities will<br />

appear in 2008 and 2009, and will be validated, subsequently, in the 2008 National<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Report to be published by the EPA. Effects <strong>of</strong> possible reduced government<br />

spending on the delivery <strong>of</strong> the National Development Plan may further impinge on<br />

the generation <strong>of</strong> C&D waste into the future.<br />

It is reasonable to relate the current uncertainty and challenges in the Irish economy<br />

to an uncertainty in quantities <strong>of</strong> C&D waste to be generated in the coming years.<br />

Irrespective <strong>of</strong> the quantities <strong>of</strong> waste that will be generated in the future, continued<br />

progress must be made in C&D waste prevention, minimisation, reuse and recycling.<br />

39.1.1 Prevention <strong>of</strong> C&D <strong>Waste</strong> – General Overview<br />

While recycling <strong>of</strong> C&D waste has the benefit <strong>of</strong> controlling the extent <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

disposal and reducing overall transportation costs, prevention is the most desirable<br />

605<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


approach to waste management, since the elimination <strong>of</strong> waste removes the need for<br />

subsequent handling, transportation and treatment <strong>of</strong> discarded material.<br />

Furthermore waste prevention alleviates pressure on limited natural resources.<br />

The management <strong>of</strong> C&D waste should reflect the waste management hierarchy, with<br />

waste prevention and minimisation being the first priority succeeded by reuse and<br />

recycling. Prevention is financially advantageous as it reduces the purchase <strong>of</strong><br />

construction materials and obviates the need to remove wastes from site. By<br />

examining ways <strong>of</strong> eliminating or reducing waste, the construction industry can<br />

achieve significant improvements in pr<strong>of</strong>itability at a time when pressure to hold<br />

down costs has never been greater.<br />

Conscious efforts by players in the construction industry can lead to improved waste<br />

prevention in this area. For instance, certain purchasing procedures can greatly<br />

contribute in the prevention <strong>of</strong> C&D waste. Examples include:<br />

606<br />

� Ensuring materials are ordered on an “as needed” basis to prevent over<br />

supply to site;<br />

� Purchasing coverings, panelling or other materials in shape, dimensions and<br />

form that minimises the creation <strong>of</strong> excessive scrap waste on site;<br />

� Ensuring correct storage and handling <strong>of</strong> construction materials to minimise<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> damaged materials/waste;<br />

� Ensuring correct sequencing <strong>of</strong> operations;<br />

� Assigning individual responsibility to sub-contractors for the purchase <strong>of</strong> raw<br />

materials and for the management <strong>of</strong> wastes arising from their activities,<br />

thereby ensuring that available resources are not expended in an extravagant<br />

manner at the expense <strong>of</strong> the main contractor;<br />

� Renovation which retains and repairs existing structural and decorative<br />

elements, with the introduction only where necessary <strong>of</strong> new items, also<br />

contributes greatly to a reduction in C&D waste arisings.<br />

� Material that is generated should be reused on site or salvaged for<br />

subsequent reuse to the greatest extent possible and disposal should only be<br />

considered as a last resort. Excavated spoil/topsoil should be carefully set<br />

aside and used as landscaping material in completed developments.<br />

With the exception <strong>of</strong> developments where planning conditions impose certain waste<br />

management policies, the above basic principles <strong>of</strong> waste prevention are largely at<br />

the discretion <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition contractors, and while some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

measures outlined present economic benefits, it seems likely that the high demand<br />

for developments in recent years, and associated aggressive construction/demolition<br />

project programmes may have drawn the focus away from such waste prevention<br />

measures.<br />

The boom in the construction industry driven by a high demand for development over<br />

recent years and the associated lucrative prices leveraged by contractors for<br />

construction projects might also have overshadowed any policies in place.<br />

29/09/09


39.1.2 Recycling <strong>of</strong> C&D <strong>Waste</strong> – General Overview<br />

The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council was set up as a voluntary<br />

industry body. The objective <strong>of</strong> the Council was to implement the recommendations <strong>of</strong><br />

Task Force B4 'Recycling <strong>of</strong> Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>' in particular the<br />

following key areas:<br />

607<br />

� Organise, monitor, report, research, promote and demonstrate best practice.<br />

� Implement the recommendations and action plan from Task Force B4.<br />

� Develop schemes to motivate and reward companies who commit themselves<br />

to reducing waste going to landfill.<br />

� Organise regional and national training programmes.<br />

� Develop and encourage support for demonstration projects.<br />

� Issue Annual and appropriate Interim reports on progress<br />

� To achieve in a tiered approach the targets set out in "Changing Our Ways".<br />

� To gather and issue relevant statistics.<br />

� To set up an appropriate scheme to identify those companies or groups<br />

engaged in successful best practice schemes.<br />

� To advise Government on policy issues.<br />

� To seek fiscal support at National & EU Level for <strong>Waste</strong> / Recycling infrastructural<br />

projects.<br />

The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for<br />

Construction and Demolition Projects were published by the Minister for the<br />

Environment, Heritage and Local Government in 2006. The purpose <strong>of</strong> these<br />

Guidelines is to promote an integrated approach to construction and demolition<br />

(C&D) waste management, throughout the duration <strong>of</strong> a project for example:<br />

� Excavated spoil/topsoil can be used as landscaping material;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> timber can be recycled as shuttering or hoarding;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> concrete as fill material for roads or in the manufacture <strong>of</strong> new concrete<br />

when arising at source.<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the policies that influence C&D waste management are presented in<br />

subsequent Annexes. All <strong>of</strong> the policies outlined have influenced C&D waste<br />

prevention and recycling in some manner, albeit, in some cases, marginally.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


40.0 National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Council - Ireland<br />

40.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council was set up as a voluntary<br />

industry body. The role <strong>of</strong> the Council is to provide a framework to achieve compliance<br />

with the targets as set out by the Minister for the Environment and Local Government<br />

in the <strong>Policy</strong> Document 'Changing Our Ways (1998) 738 and such other policies as may<br />

be set from time to time by the Government 739. The objective <strong>of</strong> the Council was to<br />

implement the recommendations <strong>of</strong> Task Force B4 'Recycling <strong>of</strong> Construction and<br />

Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>'. The Council also carries out research, prepares action plans and<br />

gives advice and guidance in relation to all matters <strong>of</strong> Construction and Demolition<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> and makes recommendations on the measures/steps that might be taken to<br />

ensure compliance with statutory requirements.<br />

40.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment and Local Government published “Changing our<br />

Ways” in September 1998. The document addressed the substantial increase in<br />

waste generation in Ireland and the over dependence on landfill as a waste<br />

management vehicle. The document acknowledged the lack <strong>of</strong> progress in the more<br />

desirable options including prevention and minimisation<br />

minimisation.<br />

minimisation<br />

The document identified the construction sector as having the primary responsibility<br />

to ensure the environmentally sound management <strong>of</strong> C&D waste. In May 2001, the<br />

Forum for the Construction Industry through Task Force B4 released its final report<br />

entitled Recycling <strong>of</strong> Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> 740 . This document contained<br />

66 recommendations on C&D waste management. These recommendations<br />

identified the need for the industry to develop environmental sustainability policies<br />

addressing C&D waste prevention or reduction. One <strong>of</strong> these recommendations was<br />

the formation <strong>of</strong> a national council for C&D waste management.<br />

In December 2001, the Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government<br />

accepted the recommendations <strong>of</strong> Task Force B4 and authorised the establishment<br />

<strong>of</strong> the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council.<br />

738 DoEHLG (1998) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> - Changing our Ways, September 1998.<br />

739 Previous examples include: DoEHLG (2002) Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong> – Delivering Change;<br />

DoEHLG (2004) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> – Taking Stock and Moving Forward.<br />

740 Construction Industry – Task Force (2001) Recycling <strong>of</strong> Construction & Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>, B4<br />

Report.<br />

608<br />

29/09/09


40.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council (NCDWC) was established<br />

on June 20th 2002.<br />

40.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council has been established by the<br />

Forum for the Construction Industry on the recommendation <strong>of</strong> the Task Force B4<br />

(Recycling <strong>of</strong> Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>) as approved by the Minister for<br />

Environment and Local Government in his letter dated the 11th December 2001.<br />

In September 2004, a Voluntary Industry Initiative was launched which called on each<br />

participant in the construction industry to commit to a series <strong>of</strong> actions, to promote<br />

waste prevention, reduction, reuse and recycling. The initiative received 100%<br />

endorsement from all key stakeholders involved in the Council and its voluntary<br />

approach was seen as a positive step towards achieving the targets outlined in<br />

“Changing Our Ways”.<br />

The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council liaises with Government and<br />

regulatory bodies on policy issues.<br />

The Council originally established five Sub Committees to assist with major bodies <strong>of</strong><br />

work:<br />

609<br />

� Sub Committee A - Infrastructure & Facilities;<br />

� Sub Committee B - Markets for Recycled Materials & Specifications;<br />

� Sub Committee C - Project Best Practice & <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>;<br />

� Sub Committee D - <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Regulatory Framework;<br />

� Sub Committee E - Information, Public Awareness & Funding<br />

The Council has since rearranged the Sub Committees as follows:<br />

� Sub Committee A – Infrastructure, Facilities and Marketing;<br />

� Sub Committee B - Regulatory Framework and Project Best Practice;<br />

� Sub Committee E - Information, Public Awareness & Funding<br />

In the National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme (NWPP) ‘Outline Work Plan 2004 to<br />

2008 741, the construction and demolition sector being a significant generator <strong>of</strong><br />

waste was highlighted. It was further stated that the NWPP would collaborate with the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council in developing improved<br />

recording and reporting mechanisms for construction and demolition waste<br />

management, as good data is a prerequisite for a waste prevention programme. It<br />

741 EPA (2004) National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme (NWPP) Outline Work Plan 2004 to 2008, April<br />

2004, Wexford: EPA.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


was further proposed that in addition to the EPA’s participation on the NCDWC,<br />

additional input will be provided under the NWPP.<br />

40.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

Data pertaining to performance monitoring in terms <strong>of</strong> waste prevention and recycling<br />

is sparse. No conclusive data was found relating the efforts <strong>of</strong> the National<br />

Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council to metrics on C&D waste prevention and<br />

recycling.<br />

However, the National <strong>Waste</strong> Reports published by the EPA contain data and findings<br />

on C&D waste management. Estimated annual quantities <strong>of</strong> C&D waste generated in<br />

Ireland are provided in such publications. Commentary is also provided on the affect<br />

<strong>of</strong> principle waste management policies on C&D waste arisings. There has been an<br />

upward trend in the generation <strong>of</strong> C&D waste in Ireland up to 2007 (latest National<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Report published by the EPA 742). This does not necessarily indicate that waste<br />

prevention measures have not been successful; rather it is reasonable to suggest that<br />

C&D waste prevention has not equalled C&D waste growth over the period <strong>of</strong><br />

economic boom in Ireland.<br />

40.5.1 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council have published annual<br />

reports as follows:<br />

610<br />

� NCDWC Annual Report 2002/2003; 743<br />

� NCDWC Annual Report 2003/2004; 744 and<br />

� NCDWC Annual Report 2004/2005. 745<br />

An annual report has not been published for 2006/2007, due to discontinuity in<br />

resources available to the Council.<br />

These annual reports are available to the public (can be downloaded from the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council’s website).<br />

Furthermore, the <strong>Waste</strong> Reports published by the EPA provide data on C&D waste<br />

arisings and comments on the effect <strong>of</strong> waste policies.<br />

The 2006 <strong>Waste</strong> Report includes the following statement -“The capacity <strong>of</strong> the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council to make rapid progress towards<br />

these objectives should be reviewed”. The objectives referred to being the targets set<br />

742 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Wexford: EPA.<br />

743 NCDWC (2003) Annual Report 2002/2003, Dublin: National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Council.<br />

744 NCDWC (2004) NCDWC Annual Report 2003/2004, Dublin: National Construction and Demolition<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Council.<br />

745 NCDWC (2005) NCDWC Annual Report 2004/2005, Dublin: National Construction and Demolition<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Council.<br />

29/09/09


out in national policy and in the industry’s own voluntary initiative for the improved<br />

management <strong>of</strong> C&D waste.<br />

The following paragraph has also been taken from the 2006 <strong>Waste</strong> Report published<br />

by the EPA:<br />

611<br />

“The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council launched a<br />

voluntary construction industry initiative to prevent, minimise and recycle<br />

construction and demolition waste 2004. The initiative set out a number <strong>of</strong><br />

objectives to be achieved by a range <strong>of</strong> stakeholders. While making good<br />

progress in certain areas, it is clear that the Council suffers from a lack <strong>of</strong><br />

dedicated resources and has been supported to date by a part-time<br />

secretariat at the Construction Industry Federation. Based on the findings<br />

presented in chapter 7, and given the lack <strong>of</strong> reliable data on the generation<br />

and management <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition waste, it is recommended<br />

that the voluntary mandate <strong>of</strong> the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Council be independently and impartially reviewed, with a view to ensuring<br />

that the Council represents the best possible model for achieving best<br />

practise in resource efficiency and waste management in the large and<br />

economically important construction sector. The onus should be placed on the<br />

Council to demonstrate that the industry has achieved “substantial progress<br />

(on recycling) through voluntary effort” and to make the case for continued<br />

financial support by Government and public bodies”<br />

It is clear from the above extract that the structure and resourcing <strong>of</strong> the National<br />

Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council needs streamlining to facilitate necessary<br />

continued progress in C&D waste management and in particular the more desirable<br />

approach <strong>of</strong> waste prevention.<br />

40.6 Environmental Benefits<br />

The establishment <strong>of</strong> the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council has<br />

promoted construction and demolition waste prevention, minimisation, reuse and<br />

recycling. The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Plans for Construction and Demolition Projects, which were drawn up following<br />

recommendations made by two sub-committees <strong>of</strong> the National Construction and<br />

Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council. The NCDWC had a very high level <strong>of</strong> support from all<br />

organisations and pr<strong>of</strong>essional bodies involved in the construction industry and all<br />

took a proactive role in contributing to the consultative process which led to the<br />

delivery <strong>of</strong> the C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan guidelines. The NCDWC called upon all<br />

involved in the construction industry to support and implement the guidelines on<br />

projects.<br />

The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for<br />

Construction and Demolition Projects were published by the Minister for the<br />

Environment, Heritage and Local Government in 2006 and formally endorsed by the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council. These guidelines are designed<br />

to influence the management <strong>of</strong> C&D waste on construction sites.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


40.6.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

The scale <strong>of</strong> the environmental benefits provided as a result <strong>of</strong> the work <strong>of</strong> the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council is difficult to judge due to the<br />

lack <strong>of</strong> sound available information on C&D waste management in Ireland.<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> C&D waste prevention and minimisation; one <strong>of</strong> the objectives <strong>of</strong> the<br />

NCDWC was the preparation <strong>of</strong> a manual titled ‘C&D <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation Guide’. A<br />

Public tender to procure a company to undertake this work was conducted in early<br />

2006. It has since been reported that a ‘C&D <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation Guide’ has been<br />

completed, however the manual has not received the approval <strong>of</strong> all the Council’s<br />

Sub-Committees. As a result the ‘C&D <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation Guide’ has not been<br />

published by the Council. Had this guide/manual been published, it is likely that it<br />

would have impacted positively on C&D waste prevention and thus the environment.<br />

This guide/manual will now need to be revised to take account <strong>of</strong> the new <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Permit Regulations.<br />

It is hoped that the issue <strong>of</strong> more accurate site management reducing the necessity<br />

for returned concrete surpluses can be addressed through the publication <strong>of</strong> the ‘C&D<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation Guide’ 746.<br />

40.6.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

Again, the scale <strong>of</strong> the environmental benefits provided as a result <strong>of</strong> the work <strong>of</strong> the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council is difficult to judge due to the<br />

lack <strong>of</strong> sound available information on C&D waste management in Ireland.<br />

The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council has promoted and<br />

accelerated the recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> C&D waste thus reducing the industry’s<br />

previous dependence on landfill as a waste management tool. In particular, Subcommittee<br />

B within the NCDWC was formed to examine the issues associated with<br />

Markets and Specifications for C&D waste.<br />

In June 2004, new specifications were introduced by the NRA, which allow the use <strong>of</strong><br />

recycled materials for sub-base applications. Sub-Committee B worked with the NRA<br />

in the promotion <strong>of</strong> the revised specifications. This was a major development as it<br />

provided an incentive for recycling concrete. Designers can now specify to the<br />

EN13242 standard thereby assuring clients that recycled materials are subject to a<br />

similar production control system as virgin aggregates.<br />

In 2004, the Council produced a non-technical report <strong>of</strong> the revised specifications for<br />

distribution to relevant organisations. This correspondence included a request that<br />

consideration be given to the use <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate.<br />

The Homebond House Building Manual was identified by Sub-Committee B as a<br />

further source for highlighting the potential for reusing recycled concrete in non<br />

structural applications. The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council is<br />

746 Irish Concrete Federation, Annual Report 2007.<br />

612<br />

29/09/09


currently working in this area and intend to execute some case studies pertaining to<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> recycled concrete in house building projects.<br />

The Irish Concrete Federation remains an active member <strong>of</strong> the National Construction<br />

and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council and Sub Committee A which is researching the barriers<br />

to and incentives required for improving recycling/recovery <strong>of</strong> inert C&D waste<br />

streams. 747<br />

40.7 Implementation Costs<br />

The costs associated with the establishment, operation and management <strong>of</strong> the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council are borne directly by the<br />

Construction Industry Federation and other Council members. The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Environment, Heritage and Local Government has also provided financial support.<br />

However, the Council has experienced funding problems since its establishment. It<br />

has been reported that a number <strong>of</strong> members have defaulted on funding<br />

commitments. Lack <strong>of</strong> funding has been reported as a significant factor which has<br />

adversely affected the continued success <strong>of</strong> the Council in recent years.<br />

40.8 Response from Public and Industry<br />

The NCDWC has received support from all organisations and pr<strong>of</strong>essional bodies<br />

involved in the construction industry and all have appeared to take a proactive role in<br />

contributing to the development <strong>of</strong> guidelines such as those related to C&D <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans.<br />

However, it has been reported that the response from industry has deteriorated in<br />

recent times. The lack <strong>of</strong> funding coupled with the downturn in the construction<br />

industry may have contributed to this deterioration.<br />

40.9 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The NCDWC is a voluntary industry body, funded and driven by the Construction<br />

Industry and other council members. It is thereby ideally placed to align its core<br />

objectives (improved C&D waste prevention, minimisation, reuse and recycling) with<br />

the latest technical changes and innovation in the construction industry. Indeed it is<br />

probable that the focus <strong>of</strong> the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council on<br />

waste prevention, minimisation, reuse and recycling has encouraged the use <strong>of</strong> new<br />

technologies and innovation in construction and demolition activities, aimed at<br />

improving waste management in the industry.<br />

40.10 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council represents the efforts <strong>of</strong> the<br />

entire construction industry. Information and publications are available to all actors in<br />

the industry, as is membership and attendance at workshop events to promote C&D<br />

747 Irish Concrete Federation, Annual Report 2007.<br />

613<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


waste prevention, minimisation, reuse and recycling. It is therefore considered that<br />

there are no distributional consequences associated with this C&D waste policy.<br />

40.11 Complementary Policies<br />

The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for<br />

Construction and Demolition Projects were published by the Minister for the<br />

Environment, Heritage and Local Government in 2006 and formally endorsed by the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council.<br />

40.12 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The effect <strong>of</strong> the establishment <strong>of</strong> the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Council on the cost <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition to the public and industry is<br />

difficult to measure due to the other variables (e.g. supply and demand) that<br />

influence construction and demolition costs. The NCDWC has contributed to improved<br />

management <strong>of</strong> C&D waste through the preparation <strong>of</strong> guidelines, workshops and<br />

continuous consultation with the industry. It is likely that any cost savings associated<br />

with improved C&D waste management have percolated through to customers in a<br />

now significantly more competitive sector.<br />

40.13 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The establishment <strong>of</strong> the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council is a<br />

voluntary initiative by the construction industry and as such evasion and enforcement<br />

are not relevant.<br />

40.14 Lessons Learned<br />

It is likely that the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council would have<br />

had more success in delivering its objectives, as set out in the industry voluntary<br />

initiative, had it not experienced problems relating to lack <strong>of</strong> funding and dedicated<br />

human resources.<br />

Improved data collection in terms <strong>of</strong> waste arisings and in the success <strong>of</strong> measures<br />

implemented on construction sites to prevent, minimise, reuse and recycle C&D is<br />

required going forward in order to evaluate the performance <strong>of</strong> the NCDWC.<br />

Further mechanisms need to be built into the Council so that differences <strong>of</strong> opinion <strong>of</strong><br />

the Sub-Committees can be resolved in a timely manner in the interests <strong>of</strong> the<br />

delivery <strong>of</strong> C&D waste prevention, minimisation, reuse and recycling targets. As<br />

mentioned earlier, differences <strong>of</strong> opinion have affected the delivery <strong>of</strong> a ‘C&D <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Minimisation Guide’, work that is completed but not published.<br />

The NCDWC is part funded and driven by the construction industry; the downturn in<br />

the construction industry may have a negative effect on the activity <strong>of</strong> the council in<br />

the continued pursuit <strong>of</strong> its goals (prevention, minimisation, reuse and recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

C&D waste) due to a decrease in funding, energy and enthusiasm.<br />

In the future, greater strides could be made in the validation <strong>of</strong> measures, by way <strong>of</strong><br />

pilot projects, to prevent C&D waste generation by improved focus on the common<br />

614<br />

29/09/09


goals that are shared by the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council and<br />

The National <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme run by the EPA.<br />

Finally, the funding problems and the lack <strong>of</strong> strong support could perhaps be<br />

overcome if the NCDWC’s work was in support <strong>of</strong> objectives which were made binding<br />

upon the industry. The absence <strong>of</strong> any binding requirements has possibly led to<br />

industry taking the view that firm action is not actually necessary.<br />

In summary, in light <strong>of</strong> the recent turbulence in the construction industry and the<br />

financial difficulties faced by the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council,<br />

significant restructuring is required to invigorate this voluntary body to further improve<br />

C&D waste management in Ireland. Members <strong>of</strong> the Council have reported that their<br />

founding objectives have been achieved. However there is significant research<br />

needed on the barriers and incentives required for improving recycling /recovery <strong>of</strong><br />

C&D waste streams, and momentum has essentially stalled.<br />

615<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


41.0 Landfill Levy - Ireland<br />

41.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The Government introduced a levy <strong>of</strong> €15 per tonne on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste on 1 June<br />

2002 under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) Regulations 2002. On the 1 July<br />

2008, the landfill levy rate was increased to €20 per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong> at<br />

authorised landfill facilities.<br />

In relation to Construction and Demolition waste there are a number <strong>of</strong> disposal<br />

activities that are exempt from the landfill levy charge, (although a gate fee will still be<br />

in effect, albeit a reduced gate fee in most cases), provided the material is not<br />

destined for disposal and is used for landfill site engineering, restoration or<br />

remediation purposes. These are:<br />

616<br />

� Non-hazardous waste from C&D activity comprising concrete, bricks, tiles, road<br />

planning’s etc. with a particle size <strong>of</strong> 150mm or less;<br />

� Excavation spoil comprising clay, sand, gravel or stone;<br />

� Dredge spoil from inland waterways and harbours.<br />

41.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The landfill levy was introduced to encourage the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill<br />

and generate revenues that can be applied in support <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

prevention/minimisation and recycling initiatives. The Irish <strong>Waste</strong> System operates a<br />

“waste hierarchy” whereby waste is preferably not produced in the first place<br />

(prevention), re-use or recycling is the next favourable option, then if this is not an<br />

option waste is incinerated (with energy recovery) and finally landfill is the least<br />

favoured option and currently the only option taxed.<br />

The landfill levy emerged, and has evolved in the following way:<br />

� 1998 1998 - Changing Our Ways, published in 1998, sets out the Government policy<br />

on waste management. It focuses on the need for a very significant reduction<br />

in our reliance on landfill, in favour <strong>of</strong> integrated waste management services<br />

and infrastructure that will deliver ambitious waste recycling and recovery<br />

targets. Changing Our Ways also emphasises the need for producers <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

to bear the full costs <strong>of</strong> waste collection, treatment and disposal, in<br />

accordance with the Polluter Pays Principle. The target set in the Changing Our<br />

Ways policy document for C & D waste was 50% recycled by 2003 and 85% by<br />

2013. In response to this the Government decided to introduce a landfill levy<br />

in 2002, to encourage the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill.<br />

� 2002 2002 2002 – A levy <strong>of</strong> €15 per tonne on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste was introduced on 1<br />

June 2002 under the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) Regulations 2002.<br />

The levy was designed to encourage the diversion <strong>of</strong> C&D waste away from<br />

disposal at landfill and generate revenues that can be applied in support <strong>of</strong><br />

29/09/09


617<br />

waste minimisation and recycling initiatives. All levies are remitted to the<br />

Environment Fund.<br />

� 2006 2006 - As a penalty for those who illegally deposit waste, the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) (Amendment) Regulations 2006 introduced a levy<br />

<strong>of</strong> €20 per tonne for each tonne <strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong> at unauthorised facilities<br />

on and from 28 July 2006. This means that persons responsible for the illegal<br />

deposition must pay the levy and remove the waste, as required by Section 60<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> Direction, and remediate the land, apart from any other penalties that<br />

may be imposed through the courts.<br />

� 2008 2008 2008 - As <strong>of</strong> 1 July 2008, the Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local<br />

Government increased the landfill levy, using the power available to him under<br />

the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Acts. The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Landfill Levy) Order<br />

2008 amends section 73(3) <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Acts 1996 to 2008 to<br />

allow for the landfill levy to be increased from €15 per tonne to €20 per tonne<br />

for each tonne <strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong> at an authorised landfill facility.<br />

� 2008 2008 2008 (August) (August) (August) – Regulatory Impact Assessment (RIA) was undertaken on the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> a <strong>Waste</strong> Facility Levy (WFL). This would include a significant<br />

immediate increase to the landfill levy, with the upper limits <strong>of</strong> the levy also to<br />

be significantly increased. Furthermore, the landfill levy is to be broadened to<br />

a waste facility levy – encompassing incineration. The ‘broadened’ levy is to be<br />

known as a “waste facility” levy. The RIA for a <strong>Waste</strong> Facility Levy (WFL) was<br />

forwarded to interested parties on the 29th <strong>of</strong> August for comment; the results<br />

<strong>of</strong> the RIA are not currently available to the public.<br />

41.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The policy was introduced in 2002.<br />

41.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

� The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage and Local Government;<br />

The <strong>Department</strong> introduces draft and final regulations pertaining to the<br />

continued operation <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy provided for in the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Acts. The <strong>Department</strong> controls and manages the Environmental levy generated<br />

by the landfill levy and plastic bag levy;<br />

� Relevant Local Authorities;<br />

The relevant local authority is simply the local authority in whose functional<br />

area the disposal activity concerned is carried out. The relevant local authority<br />

is responsible for enforcing and implementing the landfill levy regulations in<br />

their functional regions, including collection <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy arising from<br />

disposal activities;<br />

� Local Government Auditor;<br />

The Local Government Auditor is appointed by the Minister <strong>of</strong> the Environment<br />

Heritage and Local Government to carry out, or to assist in the carrying out <strong>of</strong>,<br />

audits <strong>of</strong> the accounts <strong>of</strong> local authorities or other bodies;<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


618<br />

� Operators <strong>of</strong> Disposal Activities;<br />

Operators <strong>of</strong> disposal activities are the accountable people who pay the levy.<br />

Disposal activities include landfill facilities. A landfill facility means a waste<br />

disposal site on which the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste has taken, or is taking, place.<br />

41.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

A landfill operator is required to maintain a written record in respect <strong>of</strong> each vehicle<br />

load <strong>of</strong> waste accepted into a landfill facility for the purpose <strong>of</strong> disposal, and such<br />

records must include:<br />

� the date;<br />

� the name <strong>of</strong> the carrier;<br />

� the vehicle registration number;<br />

� a description <strong>of</strong> the waste, (with reference, where practicable, to the relevant<br />

code set out in the European <strong>Waste</strong> Catalogue);<br />

� the quantity <strong>of</strong> the waste in tonnes;<br />

� other information with respect to the calculation <strong>of</strong> the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

concerned, in the absence <strong>of</strong> a weighbridge; and<br />

� a written daily record <strong>of</strong> the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste (if any) disposed <strong>of</strong> which is<br />

considered to be exempt from the levy.<br />

Local Authorities implement the landfill levy, to the extent that they operate landfills,<br />

and are required to remit their levy liability directly to the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment,<br />

Heritage and Local Government (DoEHLG).<br />

Operators <strong>of</strong> private landfill facilities are required to remit their levy liability to the<br />

relevant local authority in whose functional area the facility is located, the authority<br />

will then transfer the revenue to the DoEHLG.<br />

The DoEHLG publishes an Environment Funds Account Report. This report details the<br />

income from the environmental levy on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste and also from the<br />

environmental levy on plastic bags.<br />

The income from the Landfill levy is a direct measure <strong>of</strong> all waste being disposed <strong>of</strong> in<br />

landfill. This allows the DoEHLG to examine if this levy actually disincentives waste<br />

contractors (public and private) from disposing <strong>of</strong> waste in landfills. However, the<br />

income from the Landfill levy is not a measure <strong>of</strong> C&D waste used for engineered<br />

purposes at landfill facilities.<br />

41.6 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The effect on prevention <strong>of</strong> C&D waste has not been possible to measure. Indeed, the<br />

quality <strong>of</strong> the available data would make such an estimation extremely difficult, and<br />

no survey based work has been undertaken to understand how the levy may have<br />

changed behaviour.<br />

29/09/09


41.7 Environmental Benefits<br />

The revenues generated from the Landfill Levy are paid into an Environment Fund<br />

which was established by the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Amendment) Act 2001 (No.36 <strong>of</strong><br />

2001) and is managed and controlled by the Minister for the Environment, Heritage<br />

and Local Government. The fund was established with effect from 17 July 2001. It is<br />

not clear to what extent these funds are derived from landfilling mixed construction<br />

and demolition waste.<br />

Table 41-1: Landfill Levy Income<br />

Income Income<br />

2002 2002 2003 2003 2004 2004 2005 2005 2006<br />

2006<br />

Environmental Levy<br />

on the Landfill <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

619<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

€17,868,726 €29,359,585 €26,765,514 €27,798,605 €30,750,433<br />

Source: <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage & Local Government, 2006<br />

41.7.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

It is apparent from Table 41-1 above that the revenue earned from the landfill levy<br />

increased between 2005 and 2006. In 2006, <strong>of</strong> the €30,750,433 generated in<br />

income from the levy on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste, €1,725, 866 was spent on “<strong>Waste</strong><br />

Prevention and National Market Development Group”, €408,304 was spent on<br />

“Producer Responsibility Initiatives” and €3,649,342 was spent on “Environmental<br />

Awareness” all <strong>of</strong> these aid waste prevention strategies.<br />

The Landfill levy may have been an effective instrument for influencing C&D waste<br />

management practices. However due to the exemption <strong>of</strong> the majority (70-80% on a<br />

weight basis) <strong>of</strong> C&D waste (soils, concrete, brick, stones, etc.) from the Landfill levy,<br />

this policy has probably been rather ineffective in preventing the overall generation <strong>of</strong><br />

C&D waste. In principle, the policy may have been effective in preventing and<br />

reducing certain elements <strong>of</strong> C&D waste (including plastics, cardboard and metals)<br />

going to landfill. However, the emphasis is likely to have been on improved<br />

segregation.<br />

41.7.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

The landfill levy exemption which covers the majority (by weight) <strong>of</strong> C&D waste (soils,<br />

concrete, brick, stones, etc.) has almost certainly encouraged the processing <strong>of</strong> C&D<br />

waste in Ireland in order to separate the exempt fractions from those which are not<br />

exempt. A by-product <strong>of</strong> this processing activity has probably been the separation <strong>of</strong><br />

metals and plastics which have been sent to re-processors for recycling, although<br />

many operators will have been separating metals well in advance <strong>of</strong> the levy reflecting<br />

the value <strong>of</strong> these materials.<br />

The 2007 EPA <strong>Waste</strong> Report does not provide any figures to quantify the recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

these materials. This is possibly due to the shortfall in the submission <strong>of</strong> annual<br />

reports by permitted facilities, a fact highlight in recent EPA <strong>Waste</strong> Reports. Indeed,<br />

the EPA <strong>Waste</strong> Report figures are somewhat misleading if read at face value in that


they probably understate the quantities <strong>of</strong> C&D waste still dealt with via disposal<br />

routes.<br />

Engineering applications at landfill sites have provided an available market for the<br />

recovery <strong>of</strong> the soil and stone fractions produced by C&D waste recovery plants<br />

developed by local authorities and private operators. During 2007, the EPA reports<br />

that 12,774,774 tonnes (71.8% <strong>of</strong> C&D waste collected) <strong>of</strong> construction and<br />

demolition waste was recovered and 974,934 tonnes (5.4% <strong>of</strong> C&D waste collected)<br />

was disposed at authorised landfills and at waste permitted facilities. The remaining<br />

23% represents the gap between collection and management <strong>of</strong> waste (<strong>of</strong> the order 4<br />

million tonnes). In the words <strong>of</strong> the EPA: 748<br />

620<br />

29/09/09<br />

There continues to be a large discrepancy between the reported collection <strong>of</strong><br />

construction and demolition waste and its reported disposal and recovery. In<br />

2007, there was a gap <strong>of</strong> 4,042,037 tonnes. Local authorities have stated<br />

that <strong>of</strong> 3,686 collection permit holders active in their areas, only 2,414<br />

provided an annual environmental report for 2007, a 65% reporting rate.<br />

Local authorities estimate that non-reporting collection permit holders<br />

collected up to 633,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition waste. Of<br />

active permitted (recovery) sites, only 770 reported from a total 1,688 active<br />

sites, a reporting rate <strong>of</strong> 45%. Local authorities estimate that non-reporting<br />

facility permit holders handled over 1,300,000 tonnes. This still leaves a gap<br />

<strong>of</strong> over 2,000,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste and this in all likelihood represents a<br />

general lack <strong>of</strong> attention by the construction and demolition industries, and<br />

elements <strong>of</strong> the waste industry serving it, <strong>of</strong> the need to keep good records<br />

and provide reports to local authorities.<br />

Of the 12,774,774 tonnes recovered, 2,864,045 tonnes (16% <strong>of</strong> C&D waste<br />

collected) was recovered at EPA licensed landfills. This tonnage would have been<br />

exempt from the landfill levy.<br />

The EPA does report on different recovery rates for C&D waste with data including,<br />

and excluding, soil and stones. Although the basis for the calculation is not entirely<br />

reliable (as discussed above), the differences in the recovery rates – 80.5% and 44%,<br />

respectively – highlights the relative ease, and cost, with which different materials<br />

can be recovered from the C&D stream.<br />

41.8 Implementation Costs<br />

The landfill levy in Ireland is charged per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste arriving at landfill sites.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> is weighed upon arrival at landfill sites. Liability for the levy falls on the<br />

operator <strong>of</strong> the landfill facility and the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste at a landfill triggers the<br />

requirement to pay. This cost however is ultimately borne on the waste producer<br />

through increases in waste collection costs.<br />

For the purpose <strong>of</strong> defraying expenses incurred in the enforcement and collection <strong>of</strong><br />

the levy within its functional area, a relevant local authority may deduct and retain up<br />

748 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Wexford: EPA.


to 2 per cent <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy, but any such deductions can not exceed a total <strong>of</strong><br />

€50,000, or any amount specified in writing by the Minister, per year.<br />

The Environment Fund Accounts 2007 indicate an expenditure <strong>of</strong> €388,025 for<br />

“Environmental Levy Collection Costs”. This equates to approximately 1% <strong>of</strong> the total<br />

income from the levy on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

41.9 Response from Public and Industry<br />

There is a general acceptance <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy from the public and industry, as its<br />

aim was to encourage the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill and generate<br />

revenues that can be applied in support <strong>of</strong> waste minimisation and recycling<br />

initiatives.<br />

41.10 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The landfill levy was increased in July 2008 to further discourage the use <strong>of</strong> landfill as<br />

a treatment option. The aim <strong>of</strong> the increase is to reduce the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste being<br />

disposed <strong>of</strong> in landfill and to increase recovery and recycling rates. This increase in<br />

the levy <strong>of</strong> €5 per tonne may not be effective in reducing the rate <strong>of</strong> waste being<br />

treated at landfill as at the same time the landfill gate fee has decreased by an<br />

average <strong>of</strong> €27.50 per tonne, when comparing 2007 figures with 2005.<br />

Increased landfill levies have encouraged a change in work methods or the<br />

sequencing <strong>of</strong> work elements on site such that C&D waste produced is segregated<br />

such that soil, stone and concrete fractions can be disposed <strong>of</strong> to landfills (exempt<br />

from the landfill tax) for engineering purposes.<br />

41.11 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

This policy, by way <strong>of</strong> the exemption afforded to the heavier fraction <strong>of</strong> C&D waste, is<br />

more sympathetic to C&D waste generation as opposed to other waste streams such<br />

as municipal waste. This partly reflects the view that as long as landfills are required,<br />

then if C&D wastes are not arriving at sites, alternative materials would be required<br />

for site engineering, hardstanding, and other similar uses.<br />

It has been the case that large C&D waste producers/processors and those located in<br />

close proximity to landfill facilities, or indeed those who operate landfills, have been in<br />

a position to develop markets for the exempt fraction <strong>of</strong> C&D waste, which has in turn<br />

provided them with a competitive advantage from a financial perspective. Other<br />

smaller C&D waste producers/processors may not have been able to develop such<br />

markets. Consequently, the landfill levy exemption afforded to certain elements <strong>of</strong><br />

C&D waste may have favoured larger companies over smaller companies.<br />

41.12 Complementary Policies<br />

The C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan policy is complemented by the landfill levy policy.<br />

Avoidance <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy, through waste prevention, minimisation, reuse and<br />

recycling is facilitated by the preparation <strong>of</strong> a C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan, at<br />

project design stage, in accordance with the guidelines published.<br />

621<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


41.13 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

In principle, a landfill levy presents opportunities to internalise externalities. We are<br />

not aware <strong>of</strong> any assessment undertaken in recent years to assess these on the part<br />

<strong>of</strong> Government (though see Annex 63.0). In principle, the structure <strong>of</strong> the tax – in<br />

particular, the exemptions which apply – are likely to reflect the relative externalities,<br />

but in the case <strong>of</strong> other materials, the levy may be too low. Even so, it is the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

this type <strong>of</strong> levy, and reflecting what is feasible in terms <strong>of</strong> implementation, that<br />

simple levy structures are likely to be applied.<br />

It is reasonable to suggest that the landfill levy has encouraged actors in the<br />

construction industry to segregate the heavy soil and stone fractions <strong>of</strong> C&D waste,<br />

either through source segregation on sites <strong>of</strong> origin or post processing at material<br />

recovery facilities. In many cases, the soil fraction has been used for engineered<br />

purposes in landfills, while the stone fraction (following further crushing and<br />

screening) has been recycled and used in road construction. In summary, the above<br />

activities have probably encouraged improved management <strong>of</strong> this waste stream thus<br />

contributing to reduced construction costs for roads, buildings and other<br />

infrastructural services. The data available, however, makes it difficult to demonstrate<br />

this conclusively.<br />

With regard to the generation <strong>of</strong> C&D waste by householders through the execution <strong>of</strong><br />

DIY projects, there is a temptation to discard C&D waste in the residual bin. Residual<br />

bin ‘pay by volume’ mechanisms (and the absence <strong>of</strong> any form <strong>of</strong> PBU) and the high<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> hiring skips (which will be influenced by the level <strong>of</strong> the levy), may have<br />

encouraged C&D disposal by this means. As a result the landfill levy has been<br />

powerless to influence the management <strong>of</strong> a certain portion <strong>of</strong> C&D waste generated<br />

by householders in such a way that it is readily recycled. This is not ‘evasion’ per se,<br />

but it highlights one way in which C&D waste may ‘shift’ into different management<br />

routes as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the prices facing households.<br />

41.14 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

It is the function <strong>of</strong> each Relevant Local Authority to enforce and audit compliance<br />

with the landfill levy regulations within its functional area. The levy is payable by<br />

weight which is recorded using weighbridges at the landfill facility. A relevant local<br />

authority may at any time require a landfill operator (referred to as an “accountable<br />

person” in the regulations) to calibrate a weighbridge in an authorised landfill facility.<br />

A landfill operator, when other than a local authority, must provide the relevant local<br />

authority with a full and true return <strong>of</strong> the amount <strong>of</strong> levy due not later than four<br />

weeks following the end <strong>of</strong> an accounting period. Payment <strong>of</strong> the levy must also be<br />

executed within this time frame.<br />

A landfill operator, that is a local authority, must provide the Minister with a full and<br />

true return <strong>of</strong> the amount <strong>of</strong> levy due not later than four weeks following the end <strong>of</strong> an<br />

accounting period. Payment <strong>of</strong> the levy to the Environmental Fund must also be<br />

executed within this time frame.<br />

A return shall include, as a minimum, the following information in respect <strong>of</strong> each<br />

landfill facility concerned:<br />

622<br />

29/09/09


623<br />

� the name <strong>of</strong> the accountable person;<br />

� the location <strong>of</strong> the landfill facility;<br />

� the accounting period to which the return relates;<br />

� the weight <strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong> during the relevant accounting period;<br />

� the weight <strong>of</strong> such waste disposed <strong>of</strong> that is subject to the levy;<br />

� the weight (if any) <strong>of</strong> such waste disposed <strong>of</strong> that is considered to be exempt<br />

from the levy;<br />

� the amount <strong>of</strong> levy payable in respect <strong>of</strong> the accounting period;<br />

� the method by which the amount <strong>of</strong> levy payable was determined;<br />

� in the case <strong>of</strong> a landfill facility equipped with a weighbridge, any period in the<br />

relevant accounting period during which the weighbridge was not operational,<br />

and the weight <strong>of</strong> waste disposed <strong>of</strong> during such period that is subject to the<br />

levy;<br />

� a declaration that the information specified in the return is correct;<br />

For the purpose <strong>of</strong> ensuring compliance with these Regulations, a landfill facility is<br />

subject to inspection and audit by, as the case may be, a relevant local authority, a<br />

Local Government Auditor or any other auditor appointed by the Minister or a local<br />

authority for that purpose.<br />

A relevant local authority, or any auditor appointed by the Minister or a local authority<br />

may:<br />

� enter any landfill facility;<br />

� require the production <strong>of</strong>, inspect and take copies <strong>of</strong> any records and<br />

documents required to be maintained under a relevant waste licence;<br />

� remove for the purpose <strong>of</strong> inspection or examination or any proceedings any<br />

records and documents;<br />

� A landfill operator must comply with any requirements and furnish all<br />

reasonable assistance to an auditor.<br />

A waste disposal activity operated by a private company or a body that is not a local<br />

authority is audited by the relevant local authority, or an auditor appointed by that<br />

local authority, in respect <strong>of</strong> at least two accounting periods per year, or at a greater<br />

frequency as may be requested by the Minister.<br />

A local authority must furnish to the Minister a report on each inspection and audit<br />

carried out and must comply with any direction <strong>of</strong> the Minister arising from such<br />

audits.<br />

41.15 Lessons Learned<br />

The landfill levy has probably influenced waste management practices for<br />

construction and demolition wastes (C&D) more than household waste.<br />

The levy changes behaviour <strong>of</strong> producers, as they are responsible for paying for<br />

treatment or disposal (to landfill) <strong>of</strong> materials which they produce. In this respect it is<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


easonable to assume that the landfill levy would encourage C&D waste prevention<br />

and minimisation. However, significant quantities <strong>of</strong> the heavier fraction <strong>of</strong> C&D<br />

waste (70 - 80% <strong>of</strong> overall), exempt from the landfill levy, are used for engineered<br />

purposes at landfills. In addition, in many cases this exempted material is charged<br />

into landfills at significantly reduced gate fees. According to practitioners in the waste<br />

management industry, the majority <strong>of</strong> the lighter fraction <strong>of</strong> C&D waste (plastics,<br />

cardboard, etc.) extracted in waste recovery facilities continues to be disposed <strong>of</strong> in<br />

landfill. 749<br />

The current availability <strong>of</strong> landfill capacity is driving gate fees down and an increase in<br />

the landfill levy may be appropriate to ensure that relatively low gate fees do not<br />

undermine the ongoing progress in waste prevention and minimisation. It is proposed<br />

that the landfill levy be examined with a view to making landfill more expensive. This<br />

would be expected to make economically marginal waste prevention measures (in<br />

relation to the lighter fraction <strong>of</strong> C&D waste) more attractive to waste producers. It is<br />

clear that waste management practices for the heavier fraction <strong>of</strong> C&D waste are<br />

immune to an increase in the landfill levy due to the exemption afforded to the stone<br />

and soil fractions.<br />

The use <strong>of</strong> C&D waste fines, exempt from the landfill levy, for engineered purposes<br />

(as landfill cover) has intensified odour problems at certain landfill facilities. The high<br />

content <strong>of</strong> sulphur, originating from plasterboard, in the C&D fines can contribute to<br />

the generation <strong>of</strong> hydrogen sulphide. Many facilities have curtailed the use <strong>of</strong> C&D<br />

waste fines as landfill cover for this reason. It is worth noting that many countries<br />

have banned, or are in the process <strong>of</strong> banning, gypsum from landfills.<br />

Key Success Factors <strong>of</strong> the Landfill levy include:<br />

624<br />

� Simple measure and easy to enforce; and<br />

� Political backing for implementation.<br />

Future Changes/ Modifications to the landfill levy are likely to include:<br />

� Increase in landfill levy rates;<br />

29/09/09<br />

• It is proposed that the landfill levy be examined with a view to making<br />

landfill more expensive. This would be expected to make economically<br />

marginal waste prevention and minimisation activities, particularly in<br />

relation to the lighter fraction <strong>of</strong> C&D waste, more attractive to C&D<br />

contractors.<br />

• As mentioned earlier, certain C&D waste is exempt from the landfill levy<br />

charge, (although a gate fee will still be in effect), while these materials<br />

are used positively for engineered purposes on landfill sites this<br />

arrangement may have negatively influenced C&D waste prevention<br />

749 It should be noted that this is not entirely in line with the reporting by the EPA, though neither is it<br />

completely inconsistent with it if one takes into account the difficulties the EPA faces in reconciling<br />

figures on the collection and management <strong>of</strong> waste (see EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007,<br />

Wexford: EPA and also above).


625<br />

initiatives. In other words, the landfill levy may have had an even<br />

greater positive influence on C&D waste prevention had the above<br />

exemption not been in place. However, such a hypothetical scenario<br />

would possibly have an overall negative affect due to reduced levels <strong>of</strong><br />

C&D waste recovery. What might be appropriate is a lower levy rate for<br />

such materials, though the existing situation in terms <strong>of</strong> reporting<br />

suggests one should be cautious in making such a recommendation. In<br />

the first instance, there appears to be a need to understand better the<br />

current situation.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


42.0 C & D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan Guidelines<br />

- Ireland<br />

42.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for<br />

Construction and Demolition Projects, published by the Minister for the Environment,<br />

Heritage and Local Government, provide guidance on the preparation <strong>of</strong> Project<br />

Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for certain classes <strong>of</strong> project,<br />

which exceeds specified threshold limits. The requirement for such Plans extends<br />

equally to both public and private sector developments. They provide clients,<br />

developers, designers, practitioners, contractors, sub-contractors and competent<br />

authorities with an agreed basis for determining the adequacy <strong>of</strong> C&D <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans.<br />

Project C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans should be prepared for projects in excess <strong>of</strong><br />

any <strong>of</strong> the following thresholds and in certain cases are a condition <strong>of</strong> the planning<br />

consent for a particular development:<br />

626<br />

� New residential development <strong>of</strong> 10 houses or more;<br />

� New developments other than above, including institutional, educational,<br />

health and other public facilities, with an aggregate floor area in excess <strong>of</strong><br />

1,250 m 2 ;<br />

� Demolition/renovation/refurbishment projects generating in excess <strong>of</strong> 100m 3<br />

in volume, <strong>of</strong> C&D waste;<br />

� Civil Engineering projects producing in excess <strong>of</strong> 500m3 <strong>of</strong> waste, excluding<br />

waste materials used for development works on the site;<br />

It is considered that all construction industry stakeholders – including in particular<br />

Clients and all pr<strong>of</strong>essionals such as Architects, Engineers and Quantity Surveyors –<br />

should be pro-active in relation to the systematic reduction and proper management<br />

<strong>of</strong> C&D waste, a matter which is clearly in the public interest. Project C&D <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans should, therefore, be prepared for all but minor site<br />

developments.<br />

42.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for<br />

Construction and Demolition Projects are a by-product <strong>of</strong> a Voluntary Industry<br />

Initiative launched by the construction industry in September 2004. This initiative<br />

called on each participant in the construction industry to commit to a series <strong>of</strong><br />

actions, to promote waste prevention, reduction, reuse and recycling.<br />

The purpose <strong>of</strong> the Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans for Construction and Demolition Projects is to promote an<br />

integrated approach to construction and demolition waste managed throughout the<br />

duration <strong>of</strong> a project. They are designed to promote sustainable development,<br />

29/09/09


environmental protection and optimum use <strong>of</strong> resources. The guidelines introduce the<br />

concept <strong>of</strong> project based waste management planning for construction and<br />

demolition waste.<br />

42.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for<br />

Construction and Demolition Projects were published by the Minister for the<br />

Environment, Heritage and Local Government in 2006.<br />

42.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for<br />

Construction and Demolition Projects came about as a result <strong>of</strong> work between the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government (DoEHLG) and the<br />

National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council (NCDWC). The guidelines were<br />

published by the Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government and<br />

approved by the NCDWC.<br />

42.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

It recommended that construction and demolition contractors prepare, and submit to<br />

the client, appropriate summary reports detailing the extent <strong>of</strong> waste prevention,<br />

reuse, salvage and recycling on a project by way <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> the C&D <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plan.<br />

The client should also carry out independent periodic inspection and monitoring <strong>of</strong><br />

the implementation <strong>of</strong> the C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan.<br />

Furthermore, it is recommended that C&D waste management plans prepared under<br />

these guidelines be considered by the construction and demolition sector as a<br />

potential source <strong>of</strong> data on the generation and management <strong>of</strong> construction and<br />

demolition waste.<br />

42.6 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

Evaluation studies <strong>of</strong> C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans prepared and implemented for<br />

completed construction and demolition projects were not available for this review.<br />

The intention to design and implement a C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan is included in<br />

Environmental Impact Statements for a wide range <strong>of</strong> developments including roads,<br />

hotel and <strong>of</strong>fice developments, residential developments, etc. For example, the<br />

Environmental Impact Statement for the Luas A1 line from Belgard to Saggart<br />

contains a commitment to prepare a C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan to minimise the<br />

impact on the environment.<br />

42.7 Environmental Benefits<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans on construction and<br />

demolition projects should deliver clear environmental benefits. However, as<br />

mentioned above, no systematic evaluations are available.<br />

627<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Good waste management practice - prevention, minimisation, recycling and<br />

appropriate disposal as a last resort – is an integral part <strong>of</strong> plans and actions at each<br />

phase <strong>of</strong> the construction and demolition process developed through the C&D <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plan. The promotion <strong>of</strong> sustainable development, environmental<br />

protection and optimum use <strong>of</strong> resources are key underpinning principles. As such,<br />

the development <strong>of</strong> such plans should improve management <strong>of</strong> wastes where the<br />

aims <strong>of</strong> the plan are delivered.<br />

42.7.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans introduce the concept <strong>of</strong> project based waste<br />

management planning for projects above certain thresholds and are based on an a<br />

cradle-to-grave approach to C&D waste management. The ultimate objective <strong>of</strong> C&D<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans is to organise waste management activities on a<br />

construction or demolition site in accordance with proven and best practices so as to<br />

prevent waste generation in the first instance and increase on-site re-use <strong>of</strong> material.<br />

Successfully implemented C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans, which contribute to the<br />

prevention <strong>of</strong> C&D waste, could also result in a reduction in C&D waste related<br />

nuisances (dust, windblown litter, visual impressions, etc).<br />

42.7.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

Similarly, successfully implemented C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans should result in<br />

planned-for recycling <strong>of</strong> materials which will arise in the demolition and construction<br />

phases. In principle, the approach could also encourage the use <strong>of</strong> materials from<br />

secondary sources as a means to boost the development <strong>of</strong> markets for these.<br />

42.8 Implementation Costs<br />

In many cases the developer employs an engineering consultancy to prepare a C&D<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan for a particular project. The plan is included in the tender<br />

documents issued to prospective contractors for quotation. According to an<br />

engineering consultancy source, a typical C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan would cost in<br />

the region <strong>of</strong> €5,000 to prepare, though this is likely to vary with size and complexity<br />

<strong>of</strong> the development.<br />

While there is a cost associated with the formulation and implementation <strong>of</strong> C&D<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans, significant financial incentives are available by way <strong>of</strong><br />

resultant waste prevention when current gate fees at waste management facilities,<br />

haulage and labour costs are taken into consideration. It is recognised in the industry<br />

that high transport and disposal costs serve to make the implementation <strong>of</strong> C&D<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans financially justifiably even from the perspective <strong>of</strong> a<br />

developer.<br />

42.9 Response from Public and Industry<br />

The Guidelines, which were drawn up following recommendations made by two subcommittees<br />

<strong>of</strong> the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council in relation to<br />

construction and demolition waste management plans, have gone through a detailed<br />

consultative process. The National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council<br />

(NCDWC) co-ordinated this work.<br />

628<br />

29/09/09


The NCDWC had a high level <strong>of</strong> support from all organisations and pr<strong>of</strong>essional<br />

bodies involved in the construction industry and all took a proactive role in<br />

contributing to the consultative process which led to these C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Plan guidelines. The Guidelines were formally endorsed by the Council as a key driver<br />

in improving the way in which the C&D waste stream is managed at a time <strong>of</strong> high<br />

activity in the construction sector. The NCDWC called upon all involved in the<br />

construction industry to support and implement the guidelines on their own projects.<br />

42.10 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan is prepared by the team delivering the project, and<br />

the plan is prepared specific to each project. Therefore any technological changes or<br />

new innovations, available at project design stage, are introduced and the benefits<br />

<strong>of</strong>fered are exploited to achieve the objectives <strong>of</strong> the waste management plan, thus<br />

contributing to the prevention, minimisation and recycling <strong>of</strong> C&D waste.<br />

The C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan Guidelines focus on the cornerstones <strong>of</strong><br />

prevention, minimisation, reuse and recycling and are not specific to any construction<br />

related technologies, thus allowing the guidelines to remain in vogue with the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> new technological innovations in the industry.<br />

42.11 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

A planning authority may impose planning conditions on a developer. Certain<br />

conditions may relate to C&D waste management during the construction stage. The<br />

extent <strong>of</strong> the planning conditions imposed may depend on the scale and/or sensitivity<br />

<strong>of</strong> the development. In this regard, the C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan to be prepared<br />

for various developments may have different levels <strong>of</strong> restriction imposed whereby<br />

developers are affected differently.<br />

In summary, a large development (above a certain threshold as described in an<br />

earlier section) is likely to be conditioned by a Planner to require the preparation and<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> a C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan, however a small scale<br />

development such as the construction <strong>of</strong> a domestic house is likely to evade this<br />

requirement.<br />

42.12 Complementary Policies<br />

Both the establishment <strong>of</strong> the National Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council<br />

(NCDWC), the <strong>Waste</strong> Facility Permit Regulations and the Landfill Levy are related to<br />

this policy (C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan Guidelines). As previously mentioned, the<br />

NCDWC were involved in the delivery <strong>of</strong> the guidelines by way <strong>of</strong> consultation with the<br />

construction industry. The preparation and implementation <strong>of</strong> C&D <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans encompasses the establishment <strong>of</strong> the need to acquire a <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Facility Permit for the activities envisaged and highlighted by the plan. The ultimate<br />

objective <strong>of</strong> the plan will be to eliminate/minimise the quantities <strong>of</strong> C&D waste<br />

destined for conventional disposal (not recovery) in landfill, thus avoiding the Landfill<br />

Levy.<br />

629<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


42.13 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

There is no direct effect <strong>of</strong> the policy on the price <strong>of</strong> resources. Rather, the potential<br />

for generating financial savings through improved management <strong>of</strong> wastes is likely to<br />

become more highly valued.<br />

Clearly, it is <strong>of</strong> particular benefit to contractors when all cost components associated<br />

with waste production are identified and highlighted at an early stage. This will be<br />

effective in enhancing internal cost control procedures for the contractor and helping<br />

to ensure that unproductive and readily avoidable costs <strong>of</strong> C&D waste management<br />

are reduced. The implementation <strong>of</strong> the C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans will increase<br />

ability to control/reduce waste management costs. Accordingly, the cost <strong>of</strong><br />

construction/demolition services should reflect the reduced waste management<br />

costs secured by waste prevention, minimisation and reuse.<br />

It has been established by Skoyles and Skoyles that some 18%/19% <strong>of</strong> construction<br />

materials purchased from merchants are in addition to the quantities outlined in the<br />

project contract specification (materials may be damaged in storage or by weather,<br />

incorrectly positioned/constructed, used in greater quantities than intended, lost or<br />

stolen). 750 C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans, through adherence to the guidelines<br />

provided, can play a vital role in reducing this figure thereby reducing construction<br />

costs. Clearly this would represent significant savings through reduced materials<br />

consumption. The minimisation <strong>of</strong> waste, otherwise generated on construction sites<br />

as a result <strong>of</strong> poor inventory management, impacts positively on maintaining natural<br />

resources.<br />

42.14 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The Best Practice Guidelines on the Preparation <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans for<br />

Construction and Demolition Projects were given a statutory footing by the<br />

Development <strong>Management</strong> Guidelines issued by the Minister for the Environment,<br />

Heritage and Local Government in 2007 under Section 28 <strong>of</strong> the Planning and<br />

Development Act 2000. Planning Authorities must have regard to guidelines issued<br />

under Section 28 in performance <strong>of</strong> their functions under the Act.<br />

When a planning permission includes a requirement to prepare and implement a C&D<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan, the developer is required to submit the plan to the planning<br />

authority prior to Commencement Notice Stage.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> auditing forms an integral part <strong>of</strong> C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans as a means<br />

<strong>of</strong> ensuring ‘on the ground’ enforcement at construction/demolition sites. A <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Audit represents a systematic study <strong>of</strong> the waste management practices in the<br />

project. <strong>Waste</strong> auditing allows the success <strong>of</strong> a waste management plan, in realising<br />

the goals <strong>of</strong> waste prevention and minimisation, to be evaluated. An Audit Plan should<br />

be clearly defined in the Project C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan. Summary audit<br />

reports should be sent to the appropriate local authority.<br />

750 E.R. Skoyles and J.R. Skoyles (1987) <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention on Site; London: Mitchell.<br />

630<br />

29/09/09


42.15 Lessons Learned<br />

For the purpose <strong>of</strong> this review, a number <strong>of</strong> local authorities were contacted in an<br />

effort to get feedback on the success <strong>of</strong> the inclusion <strong>of</strong> the condition to prepare and<br />

implement C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans in certain planning permissions. It was<br />

reported that definite enforcement is required to ensure that C&D <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans are actually implemented on site, and not just a paperwork<br />

exercise.<br />

The preparation <strong>of</strong> a Project <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan should involve all parties,<br />

including client, designers, contractors and competent authorities. In particular the<br />

plan should be considered at the design stage such that any necessary changes can<br />

be made to the site layout and/or landscaping <strong>of</strong> the site to accommodate the<br />

primary objectives <strong>of</strong> the Plan (waste prevention, minimisation and recycling).<br />

Designers should provide the Client at an early stage with clear advice in relation to<br />

the prevailing policy, legislation and best practice in C&D waste management. By<br />

securing agreement from the Client on the implementation <strong>of</strong> environmentally sound<br />

management <strong>of</strong> C&D waste (prevention, minimisation and recycling) at the outset <strong>of</strong><br />

the project, this commitment can be imposed on all construction industry<br />

stakeholders over the entire duration <strong>of</strong> the scheme. This ‘cradle to grave’ approach<br />

optimises the delivery <strong>of</strong> best practice in the management <strong>of</strong> C&D waste.<br />

A clear requirement would appear to be to place the preparation <strong>of</strong> Plans on a firmer<br />

footing. Many other countries have already made moves to do this (see Annexes 43.0<br />

and 48.0).<br />

631<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


43.0 Site <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans -<br />

<strong>International</strong><br />

43.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Construction and demolition site management plans are a tool used to address<br />

issues <strong>of</strong> resource efficiency on site. <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans 751 (WMPs) aim to:<br />

632<br />

29/09/09<br />

� encourage effective waste management on construction and demolition<br />

sites through adequate planning, monitoring and reporting <strong>of</strong> waste in order to<br />

increase prevention, re-use and recycling; and/or;<br />

� reduce illegal transportation and disposal (fly-tipping) <strong>of</strong> construction and<br />

demolition waste.<br />

Construction and demolition site management plans can be implemented as a<br />

mandatory requirement or as a voluntary option. Given the discussion focuses solely<br />

on policy, countries which have set up a voluntary site waste management planning<br />

systems are excluded from the following discussion.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> management plans are required before the project begins and are working<br />

documents that need updating throughout the project. The system is basically a<br />

waste data planning and reporting requirement. It is normal for document templates<br />

to be provided, either by the enforcement body or a trade body, which the contractors<br />

can choose to use, or alternatively they can submit the required information in their<br />

own format. As part <strong>of</strong> the data collection, there is usually a central database to which<br />

contractors must submit recorded quantities <strong>of</strong> C&D waste materials generated and<br />

disposed <strong>of</strong> over a particular time period. Alternatively information received from the<br />

contractors will then be input to a database by the enforcement body, thereby<br />

creating an up-to-date source <strong>of</strong> C&D waste data. Enforced reporting promotes<br />

foresight and planning prior to the project in order to minimise and recycle site waste.<br />

In some countries, reporting on greenhouse gas balances is also tending to support<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> secondary materials rather than primary ones.<br />

43.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

There is a clear trend for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans to become policy following the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> a voluntary agreement, which is <strong>of</strong>ten made between national or<br />

local government and the construction and demolition construction and demolition<br />

industry. This is still currently the situation in many countries, for example, the<br />

Netherlands, but evidence has been found to show that WMPs have been made<br />

751 Throughout this document <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans are generally referred to as WMPs, although<br />

in country specific examples they cited their country-specific name.


mandatory to varying degrees in England, Australia, Singapore, Ontario, California,<br />

Hong Kong, Japan and Brazil.<br />

43.2.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

England<br />

In England, Site <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans (SWMPs) have been mandatory (therefore<br />

considered a policy) since 6 th April 2008. 752 They have been implemented under the<br />

Clean Neighbourhoods & Environment Act 2005 in line with the Code for Sustainable<br />

Homes (which is voluntary) and Planning Regulations. They are also an extension <strong>of</strong><br />

Duty <strong>of</strong> Care which is contained in the Environmental Protection Act 1990 and the<br />

Environmental Protection (Duty <strong>of</strong> Care) Regulations 1991.<br />

SWMPs are essential for projects worth more than £300,000 (excluding VAT).<br />

However, some local authorities throughout the UK require a SWMP for smaller<br />

projects through their Supplementary Planning Documents. 753 A SWMP should detail:<br />

633<br />

� the types <strong>of</strong> waste to be removed from the site;<br />

� the waste carrier who will transport the waste away from the site; and<br />

� the site to which the waste is going to be taken.<br />

If the project is estimated to be worth over £500,000 then the following additional<br />

information is required:<br />

� the waste carriers’ registration numbers;<br />

� a description <strong>of</strong> the waste; and<br />

� details <strong>of</strong> the environmental permit or exemption held by the site where the<br />

material is to be taken. 754<br />

Australia<br />

In Australia WMPs are also integral to the planning process but their main objective is<br />

to reduce fly-tipping. 755 However, the requirements are very similar to the UK SWMP<br />

and include details on the quantity and type <strong>of</strong> waste produced, and proposed<br />

methods <strong>of</strong> disposal for each. When tendering for major construction or demolition<br />

752 HM Government & Strategic Forum for Construction (2008) Strategy for Sustainable Construction,<br />

http://www.berr.gov.uk/files/file46535.pdf<br />

753 These are documents which are part <strong>of</strong> the development plan in a given local authority area.<br />

754 The UK Statue Law Database (2008) The Site <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans Regulations 2008<br />

(No.314), Accessed 16 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.statutelaw.gov.uk/legResults.aspx?LegType=All+Legislation&title=Site+<strong>Waste</strong>+Manageme<br />

nt+Plans+Regulations+&Year=2008&number=314&searchEnacted=0&extentMatchOnly=0&confersP<br />

ower=0&blanketAmendment=0&TYPE=QS&NavFrom=0&activeTextDocId=3448878&PageNumb<br />

755 New South Wales Government, <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment and Climate Change, Know Your<br />

Responsibilities: Managing <strong>Waste</strong> From Construction Sites, Accessed 15th October 2008<br />

http://www.environment.nsw.gov.au/waste/manbuildingwaste.htm<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


projects for either national, state or local government a WMP is required to be<br />

submitted as part <strong>of</strong> the tendering process. 756<br />

Ontario, Canada<br />

The Ontario Regulation 102/94 & 103/94 was introduced in 1994. It is applicable to<br />

construction and demolition projects with a floor area greater than 2,000 square<br />

metres. Contractors working on these projects are required to submit a <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Reduction Work Plan which outlines how site waste reduction, reuse and recycling will<br />

be implemented, when it will be implemented, and the expected results <strong>of</strong> this. 757<br />

California, USA<br />

Within the State <strong>of</strong> California there are many examples <strong>of</strong> cities that have mandated<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> site plans. For example, the City <strong>of</strong> Oakland requires contractors to submit<br />

a Job Site Recycling (JSR) and <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction Plan (WRP) for any authority-led<br />

construction or demolition project worth more than $150,000. The JSR and WRP<br />

must include the following elements:<br />

634<br />

� Type <strong>of</strong> waste materials likely to be produced by the project;<br />

� Quantity <strong>of</strong> waste materials likely to be produced by the project;<br />

� Procedures for site management <strong>of</strong> waste; and<br />

� Processors which have been identified to accept the site waste.<br />

The Californian Government has stipulated an overall recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 50%. However,<br />

the Oakland authorities have not enforced this within the C&D sector believing the<br />

stream to be highly variable, thereby allowing their JSR & WRP policy to be flexible. 758<br />

Hong Kong<br />

In Hong Kong WMPs have been mandatory for all public construction projects since<br />

2000. In 2003 the requirements <strong>of</strong> the WMP were strengthened. They now must<br />

include:<br />

� Key types <strong>of</strong> waste to be reduced;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> reduction targets;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> reduction programmes;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> disposal procedures; and<br />

756 AEA Technology (2007) Developing a Strategic Approach to Construction <strong>Waste</strong>, Final Report for<br />

Defra (BREW), Accessed 15 th October 2008<br />

http://www.bre.co.uk/filelibrary/rpts/Construction<strong>Waste</strong>Report240906.pdf<br />

757 Government <strong>of</strong> Ontario (1994) Environmental Protection Act – O.Reg. 102/94, Accessed 16 th<br />

January 2009, http://www.search.e-laws.gov.on.ca/en/isysquery/fe3d3ba6-a68c-4eaa-8354-<br />

08abf6806286/1/frame/?search=browseStatutes&context=<br />

758 Gruzen Samton LLP with City Green Inc. (2003) Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Manual,<br />

prepared for New York City <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Design and Construction, Accessed 19 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.nyc.gov/html/ddc/downloads/pdf/waste.pdf<br />

29/09/09


Japan<br />

635<br />

� Monitoring and auditing procedures. 759<br />

In Japan the Construction <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Law requires submission <strong>of</strong> a site plan<br />

prior to construction and/or demolition commencing in order to outline the intended<br />

management plan for separating and recycling site waste. 760<br />

Singapore<br />

In Singapore a Site Environmental Control Programme must be submitted to the<br />

National Environment Agency. An additional requirement is to appoint an<br />

Environmental Control Officer (ECO). They are necessary on site for the following<br />

projects:<br />

� If the project cost is estimated to exceed $10 million a part-time ECO (15<br />

hours a week) is required; and<br />

� If the project cost is estimated to exceed $50 million a full-time ECO (40 hours<br />

a week) is required.<br />

This has been mandatory since November 1999 under the Environmental Public<br />

Health Regulations. However, the ECO’s role covers the following with respect to<br />

waste:<br />

� Site management <strong>of</strong> waste; and<br />

� Ensuring construction wastes are properly disposed <strong>of</strong>. 761<br />

43.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

Throughout all the countries where mandatory WMPs apply, it is the C&D industry’s<br />

responsibility to implement and administer WMPs for their projects. <strong>Management</strong> and<br />

enforcement <strong>of</strong> the policy takes place at varying levels <strong>of</strong> government depending on<br />

the country. Sometimes this occurs through the planning function, in other cases, it is<br />

the responsibility <strong>of</strong> the environmental agencies.<br />

In the UK the responsibility <strong>of</strong> enforcement <strong>of</strong> the SWMP is mainly local authorities<br />

but over-arching responsibility is held by the Environment Agency. There is a similar<br />

situation in Australia where all three levels <strong>of</strong> Government have included WMPs in<br />

strategies, but where local government is responsible for its implementation. In the<br />

USA, local government, <strong>of</strong>ten at the town or city level, assesses the submitted JSR<br />

759 Environment, Transport and Works Bureau (2005) Technical Circular (Works) No.19/2005,<br />

Accessed 20 th January 2009, http://www.devb-wb.gov.hk/UtilManager/tc/C-2005-19-0-1.pdf<br />

760 Government <strong>of</strong> Japan’s Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment (2001) Construction Material Recycling Law,<br />

Accessed 16 th January 2009, http://www.env.go.jp/en/laws/recycle/09.pdf<br />

761 Singapore National Environment Agency, Responsibilities <strong>of</strong> Occupier <strong>of</strong> Construction Site and<br />

Submission <strong>of</strong> Reports, Accessed 16 th January 2009,<br />

http://app.nea.gov.sg/cms/htdocs/article.asp?pid=1238<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


and WRPs. It has been highlighted that the implementation <strong>of</strong> the WMP policy is likely<br />

to require a greater amount <strong>of</strong> staff time, than for example a deposit refund system in<br />

conjunction with mandatory recycling rates. 762<br />

43.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

There is a lack <strong>of</strong> available research which has effectively evaluated and made crosscountry<br />

comparisons <strong>of</strong> the implementation <strong>of</strong> WMPs. Information obtained for this<br />

report has mainly come from Government websites, industry feedback and research<br />

relating specifically to WMPs in one country. The following list outlines the key reports<br />

used (references to Government and industry websites are shown as footers only):<br />

636<br />

29/09/09<br />

� AEA Technology (2007) A <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> international Approaches to <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Prevention, and Minimisation, Final Report to Defra (BREW).<br />

� AEA Technology (2007) Developing a Strategic Approach to Construction<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>, Final Report to Defra (BREW)<br />

� AEA Energy & Environment (2007) Survey <strong>of</strong> Three Stakeholder Groups on<br />

Site <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans, Report to The Construction Resources and<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Platform.<br />

� Building Research Establishment (2008) A cost-benefit analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> site waste management plans for the construction and<br />

demolition industry, Report to Defra.<br />

� B. Baetz & T. Saotome (2007) Development <strong>of</strong> Construction and<br />

Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling in Ontario.<br />

� S. Coventry, B. Shorter & M. Kingsley (2001) Demonstrating <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Minimisation Benefits in Construction, Construction Industry Research and<br />

Information Association, Publication C536<br />

� V.W.Y. Tam (2007) On the Effectiveness in Implementing a <strong>Waste</strong>-<br />

<strong>Management</strong>-Plan Method in Construction.<br />

43.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

In qualitative terms the main positive environmental outcomes delivered by the policy<br />

are to:<br />

� reduce C&D waste to landfill;<br />

� reduce overall quantity <strong>of</strong> C&D waste due to greater planning leading to<br />

waste prevention;<br />

� increase levels <strong>of</strong> re-use and recycling <strong>of</strong> C&D waste; and<br />

� reduce fly-tipping.<br />

762 Gruzen Samton LLP with City Green Inc. (2003) Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Manual,<br />

prepared for New York City <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Design and Construction, Accessed 19 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.nyc.gov/html/ddc/downloads/pdf/waste.pdf . See also Appendix 48.0.


Hong Kong<br />

Industry surveying and interviews undertaken in Hong Kong on the effectiveness <strong>of</strong><br />

WMPs showed that the two main environmental benefits were thought to be:<br />

1. Increased on-site reuse <strong>of</strong> materials, and<br />

2. Increased waste reduction. 763<br />

However, there was no actual quantification <strong>of</strong> these benefits in the associated<br />

report.<br />

England<br />

Data available on the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> WMPs comes from the results <strong>of</strong> research<br />

published by the Construction Industry Research and Information Association (CIRIA)<br />

which found that implementation <strong>of</strong> a SWMP in England results in 15% less waste<br />

onsite and 43% less waste to landfill. 764<br />

Singapore<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> statistics from 2007 show construction debris recycling rates in Singapore to<br />

be 98%. Clearly this achievement is mainly driven by the severe lack <strong>of</strong> landfill<br />

capacity but this was likely to have been influenced also by the requirement to<br />

prepare management plans and the mandated role <strong>of</strong> ECOs. Unfortunately<br />

quantifying the effect <strong>of</strong> ECOs in isolation is not possible.<br />

With few country specific examples it is clear that there is an overall lack <strong>of</strong> data in<br />

order to prove that the main outcomes listed above are actually taking place as a<br />

result <strong>of</strong> WMPs.<br />

This issue regarding lack <strong>of</strong> data could in part be related to the lack <strong>of</strong> policy<br />

enforcement, which is discussed in Section 43.11. In addition, the data regarding<br />

construction and demolition waste has tended, by and large, to be <strong>of</strong> poor quality in<br />

many countries. The nature <strong>of</strong> the material is such that the re-use <strong>of</strong> material on-site,<br />

or the management <strong>of</strong> material across multiple sites, tends to make quality data<br />

gathering somewhat difficult. On the other hand, the plans themselves ought to be a<br />

means <strong>of</strong> achieving better quality data, albeit perhaps only for projects covered by the<br />

requirement.<br />

43.6 Implementation Costs<br />

The cost <strong>of</strong> implementation falls to the construction/demolition contractor who in turn<br />

will pass some <strong>of</strong> the cost onto their customer.<br />

763 V.W.Y. Tam (2007) On the Effectiveness in Implementing a <strong>Waste</strong>-<strong>Management</strong>-Plan Method in<br />

Construction.<br />

764 S. Coventry, B. Shorter & M. Kingsley (2001) Demonstrating <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation Benefits in<br />

Construction, Construction Industry Research and Information Association Publication C536.<br />

637<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Evidence from both the UK and Hong Kong suggests that implementation <strong>of</strong> a SWMP<br />

can be a costly process. 765 This is especially true during early stages <strong>of</strong> adoption <strong>of</strong><br />

the policy when the administrative burden is likely to be greater (even more so for<br />

those companies who manage their waste poorly and who have to set up on site<br />

sorting facilities). Staff training would be required to gain skills in writing WMPs and to<br />

gain a detailed understanding <strong>of</strong> the policy in order to comply. 766 In the UK both<br />

WRAP and the Buildings Research Establishment (BRE) have set up Site <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plan templates which should increase the efficiency <strong>of</strong> the<br />

process. 767768<br />

Prior to mandated SWMPs the BRE undertook a cost-benefit analysis for Defra. This<br />

report had to make many assumptions regarding costs due to the lack <strong>of</strong> specific<br />

information available. During analysis, it combined desk-based research with the<br />

results <strong>of</strong> a small survey and extrapolated from this. The data the project did collect<br />

related to very high budget projects, being undertaken by large companies. The<br />

analysis undertaken covered domestic and non-domestic new builds, refurbishment<br />

and demolition projects. These costs had to be scaled down in order to estimate the<br />

costs and benefits to smaller companies. Output regarding the cost <strong>of</strong> SWMP<br />

introduction for domestic new builds is shown in Table 43-1. High level SWMP refers<br />

to those projects more than £500,000.<br />

Although implementation <strong>of</strong> a WMP can be a costly process in the short-term it can<br />

bring significant financial benefits to the construction company through savings from<br />

reduced waste disposal. The BRE report goes on to highlight estimated cost-savings<br />

(Table 43-2), though it could not accurately consider transport costs due to the<br />

variation from one project to another. Comparing the two Tables, it can be seen that<br />

particularly at the higher end <strong>of</strong> the project range, costs were deemed likely to be<br />

covered by savings, but that this is viewed as being less likely in small projects. This<br />

seems to be a consequence <strong>of</strong> the fact the benefits are broadly scale dependent, but<br />

implementation costs, in particular, are estimated to be less sensitive to scale.<br />

765 V.W.Y. Tam (2007) On the Effectiveness in Implementing a <strong>Waste</strong>-<strong>Management</strong>-Plan Method in<br />

Construction,<br />

766 AEA Technology (2007) Developing a Strategic Approach to Construction <strong>Waste</strong>, Final Report for<br />

Defra (BREW), Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.bre.co.uk/filelibrary/rpts/Construction<strong>Waste</strong>Report240906.pdf<br />

767 WRAP (2009) Site <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans Tools and Guidance,<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/construction/construction_waste_minimisation_and_management/site_wast<br />

e_managemen.html, accessed 12 th February 2009.<br />

768 Building Research Establishment’s Smart<strong>Waste</strong> Website (2008) http://www.smartwaste.co.uk/,<br />

Accessed 12 th February 2009<br />

638<br />

29/09/09


Table 43-1: Estimated Total Cost <strong>of</strong> Introducing SWMPs for Domestic New Build<br />

Projects<br />

Project<br />

Project<br />

Cost<br />

Cost<br />

639<br />

Ass Assumed Ass umed<br />

Average<br />

Average<br />

Cost Cost<br />

Cost<br />

Within Within<br />

Within<br />

Band<br />

Band<br />

Time Time to to Prepare<br />

Prepare<br />

and and Write Write the<br />

the<br />

SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

Basic<br />

Basic<br />

Level<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

High High<br />

High<br />

Level<br />

Level<br />

SWMP SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Implementation<br />

Implementation<br />

Basic<br />

Basic<br />

Level<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

High<br />

High<br />

Level<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

Monitoring Monitoring and<br />

and<br />

Auditing<br />

Auditing<br />

Basic<br />

Basic<br />

Level<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

High<br />

High<br />

Level<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

Total Total SWMP SWMP Cost Cost<br />

Cost<br />

Basic<br />

Basic<br />

Level<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

High<br />

High<br />

Level<br />

Level<br />

SWMP SWMP<br />

SWMP<br />

£500k £1,600k £200 £300 -£2,300 -£4,600 £500 £1,900 -£1,600 -£2,400<br />

Source: Building Research Establishment (2008) A cost-benefit analysis <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> site<br />

waste management plans for the construction and demolition industry, Report to Defra.<br />

Table 43-2: Estimated Total Cost Savings from SWMPs for Domestic New Build<br />

Projects<br />

Project<br />

Project<br />

Cost<br />

Cost<br />

Assumed<br />

Assumed<br />

Average<br />

Average<br />

Cost<br />

Cost<br />

Within<br />

Within<br />

Band<br />

Band<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Disposal<br />

Disposal<br />

Reduction<br />

Reduction<br />

Basic<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

High<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

Resource<br />

Resource<br />

Efficiency Efficiency Gains Gains<br />

Gains<br />

Basic<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

High<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

Total Total Estimated<br />

Estimated<br />

Cost Cost Cost Savings<br />

Savings<br />

Basic<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

High<br />

Level<br />

SWMP<br />

£500k £1,600k £1,200 £2,400 £4,000 £8,000 £5,200 £10,400<br />

Source: Building Research Establishment (2008) A cost-benefit analysis <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> site<br />

waste management plans for the construction and demolition industry, Report to Defra.


CIRIA research found that implementation <strong>of</strong> a WMP could result in 50% savings in<br />

waste handling charges and 40% savings on disposal costs. Although this research<br />

was published several years ago, when WMPs were a voluntary practice, it still shows<br />

in very approximate terms that the savings can be significant. 769<br />

More recent evidence from a NetRegs survey, published 6 months after WMPs were<br />

mandated in England, showed that construction companies are saving at least<br />

£2,637 per year under the WMP system. In addition to this, 25% <strong>of</strong> companies<br />

implementing WMPs believed it to have helped them win new contracts by increasing<br />

their environmental credentials. 770<br />

Although it can be argued, and is shown from the BRE, CIRIA and NetReg evidence,<br />

that in the long-term, implementing WMP will benefit C&D companies with cost<br />

savings from reduced waste disposal costs, in the short-term they require investment<br />

and could affect tendering prices. Feedback from the construction industry in Hong<br />

Kong suggests that during the early stages <strong>of</strong> implementation, levels <strong>of</strong> productivity<br />

can be impacted upon significantly. However, when all companies reach the required<br />

level <strong>of</strong> skill and expertise needed to efficiently implement a WMP, then the costs are<br />

likely to fall back, with the benefits then being more likely to exceed the costs. 771<br />

43.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Mandatory WMPs bring the issue <strong>of</strong> waste management on C&D sites to the forefront.<br />

As a result <strong>of</strong> this, and possibly the general heightened awareness <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

issues, there is currently much discussion surrounding waste prevention initiatives in<br />

the C&D sector. For example, the current EU Eco-design Directive (2005) purely<br />

focuses on energy efficiency at this stage but it is thought that future revisions may<br />

cover a much wider remit, including waste. Initiatives are also being introduced such<br />

as WRAP’s Plasterboard Programme, being run in the UK, which focuses on waste<br />

minimisation and recycling. This is closely linked to the ban on landfilling <strong>of</strong> gypsum<br />

introduced recently in the UK. The use <strong>of</strong> prefabricated building components is<br />

thought to be instrumental in preventing waste during construction in Hong<br />

Kong. 772773<br />

769 S. Coventry, B. Shorter & M. Kingsley (2001) Demonstrating <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation Benefits in<br />

Construction, Construction Industry Research and Information Association, Publication C536.<br />

770 Construction News Portal (2009) Construction Business Still Unaware That SWMPs Are Mandatory<br />

For Projects Over £300,000, Accessed 16 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.constructionnewsportal.com/construction_article6511.html<br />

771 S. Coventry, B. Shorter & M. Kingsley (2001) Demonstrating <strong>Waste</strong> Minimisation Benefits in<br />

Construction, Construction Industry Research and Information Association, Publication C536.<br />

772 WRAP (2008) Accessed 15 th October 2008)<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/construction/plasterboard/index.html<br />

773 V.W.Y. Tam (2007) On the Effectiveness in Implementing a <strong>Waste</strong>-<strong>Management</strong>-Plan Method in<br />

Construction.<br />

640<br />

29/09/09


43.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The effect <strong>of</strong> the policy on businesses depends on how it has been implemented (as<br />

described in Section 43.2.1). Countries which apply limitations <strong>of</strong> size/value <strong>of</strong> the<br />

development, which denote whether or not the policy should be applied, will most<br />

likely affect the larger C&D companies because they are most likely to take on these<br />

projects. Equally, the BRE research discussed above suggests that these are the<br />

projects which are most likely to generate benefits which exceed the costs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> WMPs.<br />

However, as an industry which faces many challenges in reducing their impact upon<br />

the environment, implementing WMPs is one way that C&D companies can improve<br />

their reputation through potentially improving their levels <strong>of</strong> work efficiency and<br />

increasing their environmental credentials.<br />

Given the potential for generating benefits that exceed costs, the net costs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

approach are unlikely to be significant for large projects. Smaller construction<br />

projects might be affected disproportionately if the policy is extended to cover a wide<br />

range <strong>of</strong> projects.<br />

43.9 Complementary Policies<br />

The most significant drivers complementing this policy are disposal levies and other<br />

forms <strong>of</strong> policy which make disposal more expensive. Where there is a cost to dispose<br />

<strong>of</strong> C&D waste an incentive is provided for companies to reduce the volume <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

they are producing. One way <strong>of</strong> doing so is to implement a WMP on site.<br />

WMPs increase awareness <strong>of</strong> waste on site and so initiatives and policies regarding<br />

product standards (Annex 47.0) and demolition protocols (Annex 45.0) help<br />

complement work towards the goal <strong>of</strong> reducing site waste, and its disposal. Finally, in<br />

countries where they exist, taxes on primary aggregates support such a policy, though<br />

as discussed in Annex 46.0, the approach has probably been less effective than<br />

levies on disposal.<br />

43.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

There is no direct effect <strong>of</strong> the policy on the price <strong>of</strong> resources. Rather, the potential<br />

for generating financial savings through improved management <strong>of</strong> wastes is likely to<br />

become more highly valued.<br />

Given the greater amount <strong>of</strong> resources needed to properly implement an effective<br />

WMP, a C&D company’s costs may increase and this cost could initially be reflected in<br />

the price <strong>of</strong> their service as it is passed onto their customers. However, as discussed<br />

in Section 43.6 this is likely to be a short-term effect. <strong>Waste</strong> management plans help<br />

companies to save money through resource efficiency and this will either be reflected<br />

in the reduced prices for which they <strong>of</strong>fer their services, or in the company’s pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

margins.<br />

43.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

A major problem with WMPs is the lack <strong>of</strong> enforcement associated with them which<br />

ultimately leads to non-compliance. A report to Defra concluded that compliance is<br />

641<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


lacking in Australia, Singapore and the Netherlands where WMPs are very poorly<br />

monitored despite them being a mandatory requirement <strong>of</strong> the planning process. 774<br />

In England, where WMPs are a legal requirement for projects estimated to cost more<br />

then £300,000, the WMP does not have to be approved, just kept on site and made<br />

available if requested. The only exception to this rule is when some local authorities<br />

require the plan to be submitted as a Supplementary Planning Document. There is,<br />

however, an incentive to comply because in cases <strong>of</strong> non-compliance those convicted<br />

can receive fines <strong>of</strong> up to £50,000. A survey undertaken by NetRegs, 6 months after<br />

WMPs were mandated, showed that 51.2% <strong>of</strong> construction businesses were still<br />

unaware <strong>of</strong> this new policy requirement. 775<br />

In Ontario, the Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment Enforcement Branch <strong>of</strong> Operations<br />

Division, and Regional and District Offices, are responsible for visiting sites, checking<br />

the plans and ensuring that the plan is being put into practise. In 2006 the Ministry <strong>of</strong><br />

the Environment undertook inspections which revealed 90% <strong>of</strong> Industrial /<br />

Commercial / Institutional organisations were not complying with these regulations. It<br />

is thought that the main reason for lack <strong>of</strong> compliance is because although it is<br />

mandatory for a waste audit and waste reduction plan to be prepared it does not<br />

have to be submitted. 776 The regulations require the documents to be made available<br />

upon request therefore relying upon a self-regulatory approach. However, there is<br />

currently no incentive for companies to comply since there is no sanction for cases <strong>of</strong><br />

non-compliance.<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> the 2003 revision in Hong Kong, the issue <strong>of</strong> evasion was tackled by<br />

increasing the enforcement <strong>of</strong> WMP implementation, increasing levels <strong>of</strong> site<br />

monitoring and control. This included a requirement from the contractor to complete<br />

and submit the WMP within 14 days <strong>of</strong> receiving acceptance <strong>of</strong> their tender for the<br />

project. 777<br />

43.12 Lessons Learned<br />

Where the policy has been introduced using self-regulatory approaches, then uptake<br />

will be lower than hoped for as long as there is no sanction in place if a case <strong>of</strong> noncompliance<br />

is identified. England has introduced the policy in this way but due to the<br />

774 AEA Technology (2007) <strong>International</strong> Approaches to <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Minimisation, Final<br />

Report for Defra (BREW), Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.crwplatform.co.uk/conwaste/assets/Publications/2006-7-Reports/<strong>International</strong>-<br />

Approaches-to-<strong>Waste</strong>-Prevention-and-Minimisation.pdf<br />

775 Construction News Portal (2009) Construction Business Still Unaware That SWMPs Are Mandatory<br />

For Projects Over £300,000, Accessed 16 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.constructionnewsportal.com/construction_article6511.html<br />

776 B. Baetz and T. Saotome (2007) Development <strong>of</strong> Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling in<br />

Ontario. Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://msep.mcmaster.ca/publications/Development_<strong>of</strong>_C&D_recycling_in_Ontario.pdf<br />

777 Environment, Transport and Works Bureau (2005) Technical Circular (Works) No.19/2005,<br />

Accessed 20 th January 2009, http://www.devb-wb.gov.hk/UtilManager/tc/C-2005-19-0-1.pdf<br />

642<br />

29/09/09


short time frame over which it has been mandatory to prepare WMPs, there is<br />

currently no evidence <strong>of</strong> fines which have been administered due to lack <strong>of</strong><br />

compliance at this stage, despite evidence suggesting around 50% <strong>of</strong> construction<br />

companies are not aware <strong>of</strong>, and may not be complying with, the law.<br />

Enforcement and penalties are vital to the success <strong>of</strong> a policy which relies upon<br />

investments <strong>of</strong> money and time from the C&D sector. Also, current evidence to show<br />

the payback period <strong>of</strong> implementing a WMP could prove to be an important financial<br />

incentive to companies to comply with the requirement. If experience and estimates<br />

thus far are indicative, then this might show that although in the short-term, there is a<br />

cost for preparing WMPs (including, potentially, in terms <strong>of</strong> productivity on site), this is<br />

likely to be more than <strong>of</strong>fset by savings from reduced waste disposal costs over the<br />

life <strong>of</strong> the project and in the longer term. The likelihood <strong>of</strong> benefits exceeding costs<br />

may diminish as the project size declines, suggesting, perhaps, a more basic<br />

alternative to a ‘full blown’ plan for smaller projects.<br />

Industry opinion in England identifies the main problem with the implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

site waste management plans as their lack <strong>of</strong> integration within the tendering<br />

process. 778 The underlying problem is that clients’ main concern is cost, and if a<br />

company which has spent time including a WMP in the tender document is competing<br />

with a company which haven’t, they may lose the work. This effect is thought to be<br />

very short-term due to the inherent savings made through implementing a WMP due<br />

to reduced disposal fees.<br />

43.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

Section 43.2 highlighted that many mandatory WMPs began initially as voluntary<br />

agreements with strong involvement from industry. This is thought to be fundamental<br />

to the success <strong>of</strong> the policy since the responsibility is placed fully with them from the<br />

implementation stage through to regulation.<br />

As identified in Section 43.9, the introduction <strong>of</strong> WMPs is given impetus by policies<br />

which make disposal expensive. These can provide the incentive to the C&D sector to<br />

ensure more waste is prevented, and less waste is sent for disposal. The likelihood<br />

increases that the savings will exceed the costs under these circumstances.<br />

778 C. Mitchell (2008) Home Truths: <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, Building,<br />

http://www.building.co.uk/regen_story.asp?sectioncode=327&storycode=3122152&c=3 Accessed<br />

15 th October 2008.<br />

643<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


44.0 <strong>Waste</strong> Facility Permit Regulations - Ireland<br />

44.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Permit) Regulations 1998 provide for the granting <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

permits by local authorities in respect <strong>of</strong> specified waste disposal and recovery<br />

activities in lieu <strong>of</strong> a licence by the Environmental Protection Agency under section 39<br />

(1) <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act, 1996.<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility Permit and Registration) Regulations 2007 and<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility Permit) (Amendment) Regulations 2008 amend and<br />

replace the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Permit) Regulations 1998 and set out procedures<br />

for the making <strong>of</strong> permit and registration applications, public consultation,<br />

consideration by local authorities <strong>of</strong> submissions in relation to permit or registration<br />

applications, and the grant, refusal and review <strong>of</strong> facility permits and registration by<br />

local authorities.<br />

The waste facility permit Regulations encourage C&D waste prevention and<br />

minimisation due to the tonnage limitations attached to the various recovery activities<br />

permitted. The prevention <strong>of</strong> C&D waste generation on a site such that the tonnage <strong>of</strong><br />

C&D waste (intended for recovery) is below a waste facility permit threshold, thus<br />

avoiding the need for a waste licence, <strong>of</strong>fers advantages from both a financial and<br />

operational perspective.<br />

In this respect, the application fee for a waste licence for the recovery <strong>of</strong> waste is<br />

€10,000 779 compared to an application fee <strong>of</strong> €2,000 for a waste facility permit for<br />

C&D applications. Furthermore, past experience in the industry has dictated that<br />

waste licence holders can expect a more rigorous enforcement regime than waste<br />

facility permit holders for a similar activity.<br />

44.2 <strong>Policy</strong> Context and Reason for Introduction<br />

The primary purpose <strong>of</strong> the waste facility permitting system is to facilitate appropriate<br />

controls on commercial activities so as to ensure good and consistent waste<br />

management practice and the implementation <strong>of</strong> high standards <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

protection.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> permits are granted by local authorities in respect <strong>of</strong> specified waste recovery<br />

and disposal activities which, because <strong>of</strong> their scale or nature, do not warrant<br />

integrated licensing by the EPA.<br />

44.3 When was the <strong>Policy</strong> Introduced?<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Permit) Regulations, 1998, were introduced in 1998<br />

providing for the granting <strong>of</strong> waste permits by local authorities.<br />

779 EPA Website – www.epa.ie<br />

644<br />

29/09/09


In December 2007, Mr. John Gormley, Minister for the Environment, Heritage and<br />

Local Government signed the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility Permit and Registration)<br />

Regulations 2007.<br />

In March 2008, the Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government<br />

amended the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility Permit and Registration) Regulations 2007<br />

by way <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility Permit) (Amendment) Regulations 2008.<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility Permit and Registration) Regulations 2007 and<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility Permit) (Amendment) Regulations 2008 came in to<br />

effect on the 1st June 2008 and replaced the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Permit)<br />

Regulations, 1998.<br />

The new Regulations (2007/2008) introduce the following primary<br />

changes/differences:<br />

645<br />

� There is more definition on the different classes <strong>of</strong> activity for <strong>Waste</strong> Facility<br />

Permits and Certificates <strong>of</strong> Registration;<br />

� The timescales to be adhered to upon receipt <strong>of</strong> valid applications are defined;<br />

� Permits may be reviewed, revoked, transferred and decisions made may be<br />

appealed to a competent court;<br />

� Procedures to deal with abandoned applications are provided;<br />

� Planning permission or a certificate <strong>of</strong> exemption must be obtained for all<br />

permitted activities; and<br />

� An activity that has no authorisation <strong>of</strong> any kind will be regarded as landfilling<br />

and hence the landfill levy will apply. This levy will be channelled through each<br />

individual Local Authority for transmission to the Environmental Fund.<br />

44.4 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> Permit Regulations were introduced by the Minister <strong>of</strong> the Environment,<br />

Heritage and Local Government. The waste permit application process is controlled by<br />

the local authorities that issue the waste permits to applicants.<br />

The latest waste permitting Regulations (2007/2008) enable the EPA to decide on<br />

whether, having regard to particular circumstances, the facility requires a waste<br />

licence or permit.<br />

Following the introduction <strong>of</strong> the new waste permitting Regulations (2007/2008), the<br />

EPA produced and published guidance literature for the assistance <strong>of</strong> local authorities<br />

in carrying out their functions under the Regulations. However, the literature is for the<br />

benefit <strong>of</strong> all stakeholders including private waste operators and the general public.<br />

Furthermore the EPA facilitated a briefing session for industry on the new permitting<br />

Regulations in May 2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


44.5 Monitoring and Measurement Techniques Applied<br />

The following section provides an overview <strong>of</strong> the tonnage thresholds applicable to<br />

the treatment <strong>of</strong> C&D waste for both the old and new waste facility permit<br />

Regulations.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Permit) (Permit) Regulations Regulations 1998 1998 1998 (Now (Now superseded)<br />

superseded):<br />

superseded)<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> the application process, the applicant identified the relevant activities from<br />

the Third and Fourth Schedules <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act which relate to<br />

disposal and recovery activities. The activities that could be permitted were outlined<br />

in Part I and Part II <strong>of</strong> the First Schedule <strong>of</strong> the Regulations.<br />

646<br />

� C&D waste recovery operations (other than hazardous waste) (First Schedule<br />

Part I - Class 5)<br />

29/09/09<br />

There were no upper limits set in the Regulations for the recovery <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

(other than hazardous waste) provided 100% recovery is achieved although<br />

the local authority would usually specify a maximum permissible quantity<br />

under the conditions <strong>of</strong> the waste facility permit.<br />

� Disposal <strong>of</strong> C&D waste (other than hazardous waste) at a facility (other than a<br />

landfill facility) where the annual intake does not exceed 5,000 tonnes per<br />

annum. (First Schedule Part I - Class 6)<br />

� A contractor was required to apply for a Certificate <strong>of</strong> Registration from the<br />

local authority when intending to temporarily store quantities <strong>of</strong> hazardous<br />

material on-site (on the premises where it is produced) which exceeds the<br />

limits <strong>of</strong> 25,000 litres liquid waste or 40m 3 non-liquid waste. (First Schedule<br />

Part III)<br />

The operator <strong>of</strong> a waste facility permit is required to maintain specified records for the<br />

activity to which the waste permit relates and must provide such details to the local<br />

authority by the 28th day <strong>of</strong> February each year.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility (Facility Permit Permit and and Registration) Registration) Regulations Regulations 2007 2007 and and <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Facility (Facility Permit) Permit) (Amendment) (Amendment) Regulations Regulations 2008:<br />

2008:<br />

These latest Regulations came into effect on the 1st June 2008. As part <strong>of</strong> the<br />

application process, the applicant identifies the relevant activities from the Third and<br />

Fourth Schedules <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act which relate to disposal and<br />

recovery activities. The activities that can be permitted are outlined in Part I and Part<br />

II <strong>of</strong> the Third Schedule <strong>of</strong> the Regulations. If the application relates to a number <strong>of</strong><br />

classes <strong>of</strong> activities, the principal activity must be identified.<br />

� Recovery <strong>of</strong> Inert C&D waste - less than 50,000 tonnes per annum can be<br />

recovered, under the scope <strong>of</strong> a waste permit, provided that the maximum<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> residual waste consigned for collection, onward transport and<br />

disposal is less than 15% <strong>of</strong> the total annual waste intake. (Third Schedule<br />

Part I - Class 7)<br />

� Recovery <strong>of</strong> Inert waste (other than excavations or dredgings comprising<br />

natural materials <strong>of</strong> clay, silt, sand, gravel or stone) through deposition for the<br />

purposes <strong>of</strong> the improvement or development <strong>of</strong> land, where the total quantity


647<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste recovered at the facility is less than 50,000 tonnes (Third Schedule<br />

Part I - Class 6).<br />

� Recovery <strong>of</strong> excavation <strong>of</strong> dredge spoil, comprising natural materials <strong>of</strong> clay,<br />

silt, sand, gravel or stone and which comes within the meaning <strong>of</strong> inert waste,<br />

through deposition for the purposes <strong>of</strong> the improvement or development <strong>of</strong><br />

land, where the total quantity <strong>of</strong> waste recovered is less than 100,000 tonnes<br />

over the life <strong>of</strong> the activity (Third Schedule Part I - Class 5).<br />

A contractor can temporarily store quantities <strong>of</strong> hazardous material on-site (on the<br />

premises where it is produced). There is now no cap on the quantities <strong>of</strong> liquid and<br />

non-liquid hazardous wastes stored.<br />

The operator <strong>of</strong> a waste facility permit is required to provide the local authority with<br />

an Annual Environmental Report (AER), containing summary information in relation to<br />

the preceding calendar year in respect <strong>of</strong> the activities concerned, by the 28th day <strong>of</strong><br />

February each year.<br />

44.6 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> permits have been issued for numerous sites since their introduction in 1998.<br />

According to practitioners in the construction industry, the process has proved most<br />

successful for the control <strong>of</strong> specified waste reuse/recovery and disposal activities<br />

which, because <strong>of</strong> their scale or nature, did not warrant integrated licensing by the<br />

EPA.<br />

However, no detailed evaluation studies on particular cases were found during the<br />

research conducted in the preparation <strong>of</strong> this review document.<br />

44.7 Environmental Benefits<br />

44.7.1 Environmental Benefits – Prevention<br />

The environmental benefits provided by the <strong>Waste</strong> Permit Regulations (1998<br />

Regulations & 2007 Regulations /2008 Amendment Regulations) include a reduction<br />

in C&D waste generation and C&D waste sent to landfill.<br />

44.7.2 Environmental Benefits Associated with Recycling<br />

The Regulations facilitate the reuse/recovery <strong>of</strong> excavated materials on the site <strong>of</strong><br />

origin and the use <strong>of</strong> excavated materials for the improvement and development <strong>of</strong><br />

land on other sites.<br />

Furthermore, the issue <strong>of</strong> a waste permit facilitates the control and monitoring <strong>of</strong> C&D<br />

waste reuse and recovery activities. The local authority, by way <strong>of</strong> monitoring,<br />

inspection and auditing, enforces compliance with the regulation requirements.<br />

Accordingly there are reduced environmental nuisances on sites that are in<br />

compliance with their waste permit conditions.<br />

44.8 Implementation Costs<br />

The implementation cost <strong>of</strong> a waste permit is borne by the facility/site operator. The<br />

payment for a waste permit is made to the relevant local authority. The initial<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


application fee is consistent from local authority to local authority; however the<br />

monitoring fee can vary from local authority to local authority.<br />

A primary aim <strong>of</strong> the new Regulations is to introduce consistency among local<br />

authorities with respect to all aspects <strong>of</strong> the waste permit process, including<br />

implementation cost. The new Regulations empower local authorities to recover all or<br />

part <strong>of</strong> the reasonable costs incurred by ongoing monitoring <strong>of</strong> compliance with a<br />

facility permit, including the costs <strong>of</strong> inspections and investigations.<br />

44.9 Response from Public and Industry<br />

The latest Regulations (2007 Regulations /2008 Amendment Regulations) which<br />

were subject to wide scale public consultation took a considerable time to progress<br />

due to the complexity <strong>of</strong> the issues needing to be addressed and will assist in:<br />

648<br />

� Facilitating recovery activities to the greatest extent practicable.<br />

� Minimising the considerable administrative and cost burden on applicants.<br />

� Harmonising administration and implementation <strong>of</strong> the permitting and<br />

registration system.<br />

44.10 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The applicant provides a comprehensive description <strong>of</strong> the proposed site and<br />

intended C&D waste reuse/recovery operations at the application stage. The<br />

applicant can avail <strong>of</strong> the latest technologies available to the market by including<br />

descriptions <strong>of</strong> improved processes and innovations in the waste permit application.<br />

The application will then be assessed by the relevant local authority and subject to<br />

the new technology/process not presenting any unwanted environmental<br />

consequences; the application may be approved by the local authority.<br />

44.11 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

All operators are subjected to a similar application process through the relevant local<br />

authority. However, in the past the application period experienced by applicants has<br />

varied from Local Authority to Local Authority. The effect <strong>of</strong> the waste permit<br />

regulations on a site or a facility is dependent on the scale <strong>of</strong> the recovery operation<br />

proposed. As outlined above, the nature and tonnage <strong>of</strong> the intended recovery<br />

operation will result in a site or facility qualifying or not qualifying for a waste permit.<br />

44.12 Complementary Policies<br />

The C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan guidelines complement this policy. The generation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan at the project outset identifies the need for a<br />

permit or otherwise. The quantities <strong>of</strong> waste estimated at the design stage, following<br />

prevention and minimisation measures, feed into the application process for the<br />

waste facility permit. A judgement on whether the site qualifies for a permit is then<br />

made.<br />

Furthermore, the C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan provides the necessary framework<br />

required for recording and reporting <strong>of</strong> data to support the waste facility permit<br />

conformance conditions.<br />

29/09/09


44.13 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The Regulations (1998 Regulations & 2007 Regulations /2008 Amendment<br />

Regulations) encourage waste prevention, minimisation (in order to satisfy tonnage<br />

thresholds) and reuse on site as well as waste recovery. Hence, it is reasonable to<br />

suggest that there is a reduction in the quantities <strong>of</strong> C&D waste being hauled <strong>of</strong>f site<br />

to landfill facilities. This effect translates to a cost reduction in the waste<br />

management element <strong>of</strong> a project. In theory, the cost <strong>of</strong> construction to the client or<br />

public should reduce accordingly, however such is at the discretion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

construction industry or is dependent on the buoyancy <strong>of</strong> the construction industry at<br />

the time in question.<br />

44.14 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The relevant local authority attaches such conditions as are necessary to ensure the<br />

proper enforcement <strong>of</strong> the waste permit.<br />

Once a waste facility permit is granted, compliance with the relevant legal<br />

requirements are checked and enforced. Checks take place through monitoring,<br />

inspection and auditing and by taking relevant enforcement action where necessary.<br />

The local authorities provide enforcement in accordance with the Environmental<br />

Enforcement Network (EEN) Guidance Manual, launched in 2005. The manual<br />

provides comprehensive guidance on environmental enforcement and in particular it<br />

provides specialist guidance on waste enforcement.<br />

Audit programmes are conducted by the local authorities to verify the data provided<br />

by holders <strong>of</strong> waste facility permits on waste acceptance, waste recovery and waste<br />

disposal.<br />

44.15 Lessons Learned<br />

The provision <strong>of</strong> the latest <strong>Waste</strong> Permit Regulations is based on lessons learned and<br />

experiences gained during the issuing and monitoring <strong>of</strong> waste permits under the<br />

1998 Regulations. For example, Sub-Committee D <strong>of</strong> the National Construction and<br />

Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Council sought a simplification <strong>of</strong> the permitting process and a<br />

reduction in the time period needed for determination <strong>of</strong> applications.<br />

Draft <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Regulations were issued for public consultation with a view<br />

to simplifying and streamlining the existing system and propose a number <strong>of</strong><br />

amendments to existing Regulations. The proposals attempted to resolve a number <strong>of</strong><br />

issues raised by the construction industry stakeholders and have the objective, where<br />

feasible, <strong>of</strong> making authorisation applications for reuse and recycling <strong>of</strong> C&D wasterelated<br />

activities a more attractive proposition for developers.<br />

By means <strong>of</strong> a discussion with the Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Association (IWMA), a<br />

view was expressed that the draft regulations published for consultation were<br />

significantly different than the final <strong>Waste</strong> Permit Regulations published. While the<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> consultation is to gather stakeholder input and reflect it in final publication,<br />

a review <strong>of</strong> the consultation process and the methods used to keep stakeholders<br />

informed <strong>of</strong> progress may be beneficial for future regulation amendment.<br />

649<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


45.0 Demolition Protocol - UK<br />

45.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The Institute <strong>of</strong> Civil Engineers, with support from the <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action<br />

Programme (WRAP), has developed a Demolition Protocol. It provides a framework for<br />

sustainable resource management within the demolition industry (although<br />

refurbishment is also included as part <strong>of</strong> the Protocol) which can be implemented<br />

through contractual conditions or the planning system. It provides methodologies for<br />

delivery <strong>of</strong> resource efficiency through a framework ‘for the assessment and recovery<br />

<strong>of</strong> demolition material and the potential for specifying recovered (recycled and<br />

reclaimed) material in the new build’. 780<br />

In practise, the Demolition Protocol requires the contractor to undertake a demolition<br />

audit prior to demolition occurring which characterises and identifies quantities <strong>of</strong><br />

materials being produced through the demolition process, identifies the potential for<br />

resource recovery, set targets for material recovery and verifies the targets are<br />

reached. A similar process <strong>of</strong> measurement takes place throughout the new build<br />

phase <strong>of</strong> the project.<br />

The Protocol is currently not made mandatory through a centralised planning<br />

requirement, and so therefore, in-line with this review, it is not considered a policy.<br />

However, to-date there is one example where it was enforced throughout a project,<br />

and due to the general lack <strong>of</strong> clear policies implemented within the C&D sector, it<br />

was thought beneficial to draw from this example, albeit on a small-scale.<br />

45.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

The London Borough <strong>of</strong> Brent Council incorporated the Protocol through their<br />

Supplementary Planning Document on Sustainable Design, Construction and<br />

Pollution Control because it ensured that resource efficiency would be prioritised<br />

throughout development. 781 Implementing the Demolition Protocol was, therefore, a<br />

mandatory requirement <strong>of</strong> the Wembley Link development project.<br />

45.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The key organisation is the planning authority that has the power to mandate this<br />

Protocol within planning regulations and drive forward sustainable construction and<br />

demolition. During the project the principal contractor is responsible for both<br />

780 WRAP (2007) ICE Demolition Protocol Case Study Wembley Link, Accessed 21st October 2008,<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/WRAP_Case_Study__Wembley_Link_formatted_2_.e66b89c1.46<br />

51.pdf<br />

781 Sonnervera <strong>International</strong> Corporation (2006) Construction, Renovation and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Materials: Opportunities for <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction and Diversion.<br />

650<br />

29/09/09


implementing and managing the Protocol, which in the case <strong>of</strong> the Wembley Link<br />

development, was Edmund Nuttall.<br />

45.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

This case study is outlined in 2 documents:<br />

651<br />

� WRAP (2007) ICE Demolition Protocol Case Study Wembley Link, Accessed<br />

21 st October 2008, http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/WRAP_Case_Study_-<br />

_Wembley_Link_formatted_2_.e66b89c1.4651.pdf<br />

� Sonnervera <strong>International</strong> Corporation (2006) Construction, Renovation and<br />

Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Materials: Opportunities for <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction and Diversion.<br />

45.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

With regards to waste prevention, implementing the Protocol led to reclamation <strong>of</strong><br />

approximately 3,800 tonnes <strong>of</strong> aggregate material which were reused within other<br />

areas <strong>of</strong> the project. The WRAP case study estimates that if site and material planning<br />

had been used to its full advantage, 384 lorry journeys could have been prevented.<br />

If materials could not be re-used on site they were sold on to be re-used, e.g. bricks.<br />

Furthermore all wood and metal was site separated and sent to reprocessing<br />

facilities.<br />

Other less quantifiable waste prevention benefits were identified through a predemolition<br />

audit which led to reclamation <strong>of</strong> mechanical plant, carpet, fixtures, fittings<br />

and traditional bricks. Procurement for construction materials focused on sourcing<br />

recovered materials. This was achieved through setting targets for recycled material<br />

procurement. 782<br />

45.6 Implementation Costs<br />

This section is considered not applicable because at this stage the Demolition<br />

Protocol is not broadly a policy, therefore implementation costs are unknown and are<br />

not detailed in the case study.<br />

45.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> recovery websites were utilised in order to enable others to re-use items that<br />

were being removed from the demolition works. Many <strong>of</strong> these websites exist but it is<br />

thought to be an immature market and under-used due to lack <strong>of</strong> awareness that<br />

such a service exists. However, it was successful in finding new users for the air<br />

conditioning units and carpet tiles. The case study also highlights that work was<br />

undertaken to find ‘creative outlets for the materials identified’.<br />

782 WRAP (2007) ICE Demolition Protocol Case Study Wembley Link, Accessed 21st October 2008,<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/WRAP_Case_Study__Wembley_Link_formatted_2_.e66b89c1.46<br />

51.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Due to the relative small-scale <strong>of</strong> the implementation <strong>of</strong> this Protocol this section is<br />

considered not applicable.<br />

45.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

Not applicable<br />

45.9 Complementary Policies<br />

In the UK, landfill tax is a key driver for this policy by increasing disposal costs<br />

therefore encouraging alternative solutions to disposal, such as on-site recovery,<br />

which is central to the Demolition Protocol.<br />

Also, product standards are likely to increase confidence in recycled materials and<br />

encourage more wide-spread on-site re-use and marketing / use <strong>of</strong> secondary<br />

materials (Section 47.0)<br />

45.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

There are financial benefits to be gained from by re-using aggregate arising from<br />

demolition for new on-site construction. Although cost savings have not been<br />

quantified in the case study, an approximate calculation can be done, taking the<br />

average price for one tonne <strong>of</strong> aggregate and multiplying this by the 3,800 tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

aggregate re-used in other areas <strong>of</strong> the development project. This results in a saving<br />

<strong>of</strong> £59,200. 783 This is a significant saving but without knowing the value <strong>of</strong> the project<br />

as a whole it is hard to know exactly how significant this saving has been.<br />

45.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

No issues were identified in this isolated example.<br />

45.12 Lessons Learned<br />

The Sonnervera <strong>International</strong> Corporation highlights the following 5 lessons learned<br />

from the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Protocol for the Wembley development:<br />

652<br />

� Planning authorities have the power needed to enforce this Protocol;<br />

� Enforcing the Protocol across all planning authorities would be more effective<br />

in ensuring a level playing field;<br />

� Stakeholder buy-in (construction and demolition companies and local/national<br />

government) is essential;<br />

� To this end, carrying out a stakeholder consultation would seem appropriate;<br />

and<br />

� Ensure that effective guidance documents are provided.<br />

783 The average price for one tonne <strong>of</strong> aggregate material was calculated as £15.60. Data was taken<br />

from the Cardigan Sand & Gravel Co Ltd, http://www.cardigansand.co.uk/pricelist.html<br />

29/09/09


46.0 Tax on Aggregates - <strong>International</strong><br />

46.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Sand, gravel and rock are commonly known as aggregates and are essential<br />

materials for the construction industry. A tax on aggregates is an example <strong>of</strong> a natural<br />

resource based tax. It is a market-based instrument with both fiscal and<br />

environmental motivations. Such taxes aim to raise revenue without distorting a<br />

country’s economic activity.<br />

The objectives for introducing a tax on aggregates vary depending upon the country in<br />

which it is being implemented. The policy can have four main effects on aggregates:<br />

653<br />

� Reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> virgin aggregate material extracted (reduced<br />

consumption leads to less disposal);<br />

� Increase the amount <strong>of</strong> aggregate re-use;<br />

� Increase the use <strong>of</strong> substitutes for primary aggregate; and<br />

� Increase the recycling <strong>of</strong>, and use <strong>of</strong>, secondary aggregates<br />

A tax on aggregates is a fiscal measure which usually works by shifting the price<br />

differential against virgin, and in favour <strong>of</strong> secondary aggregates, making it financially<br />

more beneficial to recycle aggregate and use secondary aggregate. The recycled<br />

aggregate is mainly derived as waste from the construction and demolition industry.<br />

46.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

Denmark, Sweden, the UK, Belgium (Flanders) and Italy (at a regional level) have all<br />

implemented a pure aggregate levy. 784 The main policy objectives and the year in<br />

which the policy was introduced are outlined in Table 46-1.<br />

In Denmark, the tax applies to raw materials that are commercially extracted and<br />

consumed in Denmark, or commercially imported. These include sand, gravel, stones,<br />

peat, clay and limestone.<br />

In Sweden, gravel is a very important resource due to necessity for aquifers on which<br />

much <strong>of</strong> the country relies for drinking water. It was also recognised that gravel is an<br />

easily extractable finite resource. This was leading to a shortage <strong>of</strong> gravel in some<br />

parts <strong>of</strong> Sweden. The tax was therefore introduced for environmental reasons and<br />

aimed to make gravel-alternatives more cost-competitive, therefore increasing use <strong>of</strong><br />

recycled aggregates, and reducing consumption <strong>of</strong> gravel.<br />

784 R. Bleischwitz and b. Bahn-Walkowiak (2007) Aggregates and Construction Markets in Europe:<br />

Towards a Sectoral Action Plan on Sustainable Resource <strong>Management</strong>, Minerals and Energy, Raw<br />

Materials Report, 22:3, 159-176.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 46-1: Main Aggregate Levy <strong>Policy</strong> Objectives<br />

Name <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Policy</strong><br />

Year <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Introduced<br />

Objective 1<br />

Objective 2<br />

654<br />

29/09/09<br />

Denmark Denmark<br />

Sweden Sweden<br />

UK UK<br />

Tax on <strong>Waste</strong> and<br />

Certain Raw<br />

Materials<br />

The Law Concerning Tax on<br />

Natural Materials<br />

1990 1996 2002<br />

To reduce<br />

resource<br />

extraction<br />

To increase<br />

aggregate<br />

recycling<br />

To safeguard gravel<br />

resources and water quality<br />

To increase material<br />

substitution to crushed rock<br />

and recycled material<br />

Aggregate Levy<br />

To reduce demand for<br />

aggregates and encourage<br />

recycling<br />

To compensate for<br />

environmental externalities<br />

caused by quarry activities<br />

In summary, the levy aims to reflect environmental costs in the price <strong>of</strong> aggregate<br />

extraction and encourage the use <strong>of</strong> alternative materials such as recycled aggregate.<br />

Recycled materials (if not commercially extracted again) do not fall under the tax<br />

regime in any country where an aggregate tax has been implemented.<br />

46.2.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

46.2.1.1 Material Variations in the Scope <strong>of</strong> the Levy<br />

Denmark’s ‘Tax on <strong>Waste</strong> and Certain Raw Materials’ applies to raw materials that<br />

are commercially extracted and consumed in Denmark, or commercially imported.<br />

These include sand, gravel, stones, peat, top soil, clay, chalk and limestone. The<br />

following are described by the ECOTEC report as being exempt from the tax: 785<br />

� Raw materials extracted for coastal projects to protect the beaches against<br />

erosive action;<br />

� Sea bed materials, which originate from maintenance and capital dredging<br />

projects and which are utilised as raw materials;<br />

� Residual products and waste products, which are extracted from already<br />

closed depots;<br />

� Top soil and peat, which are delivered without payment; and<br />

� Raw materials commercially extracted or imported by a business, when the<br />

annual amount is less than 200 m 3 <strong>of</strong> raw materials.<br />

Sweden’s ‘Tax on Natural Materials’, commonly referred to as ‘Gravel Tax’, applies to<br />

gravel, which consists mainly <strong>of</strong> sand, gravel, cobble and boulder size fractions.<br />

785 ECOTEC Research and Consulting (2001) Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the Use <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental Taxes and Charges in the EU and its Member States, Accessed 21 st October 2008,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/taxation/pdf/ch11_aggregated_taxes.pdf


The UK’s ‘Aggregate Levy’ applies to aggregate which in the UK is deemed to consist<br />

<strong>of</strong> sand, gravel and rock, with the following exceptions:<br />

655<br />

� Materials such as clay, slate and shale, which are not strictly aggregates but<br />

which are used for similar purposes;<br />

� Minerals (mainly for industrial use) whose extraction necessarily involves the<br />

extraction <strong>of</strong> stone, gravel or sand; and<br />

� Coal, metals and peat.<br />

The levy is applied to materials which are:<br />

� Quarried in the UK;<br />

� Mined underground in the UK;<br />

� Dredged from UK waters; or<br />

� Imported into the UK.<br />

46.2.1.2 Variations in the Level <strong>of</strong> the Tax and the Basis for the Tax<br />

The tax in Denmark is based on volume (m 3) <strong>of</strong> material extracted and the tax<br />

currently stands at €0.67 per m 3 . The revenue generated goes directly to the State’s<br />

general budget as well as towards subsidy schemes, which support waste-related<br />

initiatives in the fields <strong>of</strong> waste prevention, recovery and recycling. 786<br />

In Sweden the tax is levied on the basis <strong>of</strong> weight and the current level <strong>of</strong> tax is €1.43<br />

per tonne <strong>of</strong> extracted material. 787<br />

In the UK the aggregate levy is also levied on a weight basis and currently stands at<br />

£1.95 (€2.34) per tonne (increased from £1.60 (€1.92) per tonne in April 2008 to<br />

account for inflation). 788<br />

At the time <strong>of</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> the UK tax, there was some concern regarding imports<br />

and exports between Northern Ireland, which was due to implement the aggregate<br />

levy, and the Republic <strong>of</strong> Ireland, which was not. The discontinuity across countries<br />

was likely to have a negative impact upon the pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> the industry in Northern<br />

Ireland relative to those in the Republic. This resulted in Northern Ireland setting up<br />

an aggregate levy tax relief scheme whereby 80% relief from the tax was granted<br />

(meaning the levy costs £0.32 or €0.38) where a business registers with Customs<br />

and Excise (now HM revenue and Customs) and commits to undertaking<br />

environmental improvements on their site 789 .<br />

786 Converted using an exchange rate <strong>of</strong> €1.2 = £1.<br />

787 Converted using an exchange rate <strong>of</strong> €1.2 = £1.<br />

788 Converted using an exchange rate <strong>of</strong> €1.2 = £1.<br />

789 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Northern Ireland, Aggregates Levy Credit Scheme, Accessed 20 th<br />

January 2009,<br />

http://www.doeni.gov.uk/index/protect_the_environment/local_environmental_issues/aggregates_lev<br />

y_credit_agreement_scheme.htm<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The UK has adopted an approach whereby revenue from the tax is put into an<br />

Aggregate Levy Sustainability Fund (ALSF). This is used to deliver environmental<br />

benefits through awareness raising campaigns and promoting use <strong>of</strong> recycled<br />

aggregates, demand for which is being increased through development <strong>of</strong> quality<br />

standards for secondary aggregates (Section 47.0). Revenue is also recycled to<br />

industry through a 0.1% reduction in employer National Insurance Contributions. 790<br />

The level <strong>of</strong> tax implemented is considerably higher in the UK, as a proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

price, than elsewhere. In the UK the tax on aggregates equates to 20% <strong>of</strong> the average<br />

price for sand, rock and gravel compared to the case <strong>of</strong> Sweden, where the tax<br />

equates to only 12% <strong>of</strong> the average price.<br />

The UK recently saw an increase in the rate <strong>of</strong> the levy, but generally, the level <strong>of</strong><br />

aggregate tax has been fairly stable over time. Sweden, however, has introduced<br />

incremental increases in the tax over time.<br />

46.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

In all three cases, central government is responsible for original implementation,<br />

management and administration <strong>of</strong> the policy. Specific country details are described<br />

below:<br />

656<br />

29/09/09<br />

� The Danish Ministry <strong>of</strong> Taxation designed an amended law in 1992 and is<br />

currently responsible for the implementation and administration <strong>of</strong> the tax. In<br />

doing so they monitor the levels <strong>of</strong> extraction taking place;<br />

� The Gävle Tax Authority is responsible for the implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax in<br />

Sweden; and<br />

� HM Revenue and Customs, the revenue collecting arm <strong>of</strong> UK Government,<br />

implements and manages the UK aggregate levy.<br />

The systems rely upon commercial extractors being registered with the above<br />

organisations. These companies must account for the amount <strong>of</strong> raw material they<br />

use in order to calculate the amount <strong>of</strong> tax they must pay.<br />

46.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

This ECOTEC study compares the Danish, Swedish and UK aggregate taxes.<br />

� ECOTEC Research and Consulting (2001) Economic and Environmental<br />

Implications <strong>of</strong> the Use <strong>of</strong> Environmental Taxes and Charges in the EU and its<br />

Member States, Accessed 21 st October 2008,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/taxation/pdf/ch11_aggregated_tax<br />

es.pdf<br />

790 Defra (2006) Aggregates Levy Sustainability Fund in England 2002-2007, Accessed 20 th January<br />

2009, http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/waste/aggregates/pdf/agglevy-summary.pdf


The following study is a comparison <strong>of</strong> aggregates taxes that have been introduced in<br />

the Czech Republic, Italy, Sweden and the UK. 791<br />

� European Environment Agency (2008) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Environmental Taxes<br />

and Charges for Managing Sand, Gravel and Rock Extraction in Selected EU<br />

Countries, Accessed 23 rd October 2008,<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/eea_report_2008_2/en/Effectiveness_<strong>of</strong>_envir<br />

onmental_taxes_final_low.pdf<br />

Other notable references include:<br />

� R. Bleischwitz & B. Bahn-Walkowiak (2007) Aggregates and Construction<br />

Markets in Europe: Towards a Sectoral Action Plan on Sustainable Resource<br />

<strong>Management</strong>, Minerals and Energy – Raw Materials Report, 22:3, 159-176.<br />

657<br />

� P. Soderholm (2006) Environmental Taxation in the Natural Resource<br />

Extraction Sector: Is it a Good Idea?, European Environment 16, pp. 232 –<br />

245.<br />

� S. Speck, >. Skou Andersen, H. O. Nielsen, A. Ryelund and C. Smith (2006) The<br />

Use <strong>of</strong> Economic Instruments in Nordic and Baltic Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> 2001-<br />

2005, TemaNord 2006:525, Nordic Council <strong>of</strong> Ministers, Denmark.<br />

� HM Customs & Excise Consultation (1998) Aggregates Levy Regulatory Impact<br />

Assessment, Accessed 16th February 2009,<br />

http://customs.hmrc.gov.uk/channelsPortalWebApp/downloadFile?contentID<br />

=HMCE_CL_001429<br />

46.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The first main environmental benefit <strong>of</strong> the policy is shifting the balance between<br />

virgin and recycled aggregate consumption such that an increasing proportion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

market is accounted for by recycled aggregate. This may reduce energy use and<br />

associated carbon dioxide emissions with primary material extraction. 792<br />

Denmark<br />

In Denmark 90% <strong>of</strong> demolition waste is recycled but ECOTEC (2001) believe this has<br />

little to do with the tax on aggregates, and that the principle driver is the waste tax.<br />

The tax had little impact on raw material extraction as demonstrated by the continued<br />

demand for raw material, reflecting the low price elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand for virgin<br />

791 Czech Republic and Italy are not included in this review because these taxes are mining charges,<br />

not aggregate product taxes, and do not impact upon aggregate waste and recycling in any significant<br />

way.<br />

792 European Environment Agency (2008) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Environmental Taxes and Charges for<br />

Managing Sand, Gravel and Rock Extraction in Selected EU Countries, Accessed 23 rd October 2008,<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/eea_report_2008_2/en/Effectiveness_<strong>of</strong>_environmental_taxes_final_lo<br />

w.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


aggregate (and the fact that the tax accounts for only a small proportion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

primary aggregates price). 793<br />

Sweden<br />

Sweden has a low recycling rate but this can be explained through reference to the<br />

fact that there is very little demolition taking place, and therefore, less material to<br />

recycle. The main material used for recycling is mining waste. The proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

aggregate production from secondary material is 11%. 794 Sweden has seen a shift<br />

away from the use <strong>of</strong> gravel, but given the range <strong>of</strong> policies that have been<br />

implemented, it seems unlikely that the relatively small tax on aggregates could be<br />

the main reason for the shift. Sweden does have a substantial tax on waste disposal<br />

by landfill, currently at €47/tonne, which is likely to be influential. A far more detailed<br />

analysis than is available would be required to estimate the proportion <strong>of</strong> the change<br />

accounted for specifically by the tax on aggregates, compared to the tax on waste<br />

disposal.<br />

UK<br />

The UK has the highest recycling rate for aggregate materials in Europe. They account<br />

for 25% <strong>of</strong> the UK aggregates market (the largest market share for recycled<br />

aggregates in Europe). 795 The situation here is similar to that <strong>of</strong> Sweden where<br />

unpicking the direct impact <strong>of</strong> implementing the tax on aggregate is very difficult<br />

when waste disposal is also taxed, albeit at a lower rate for construction and<br />

demolition wastes than for non-inert fractions.<br />

Evidence suggests, although cannot be conclusive, that the tax on aggregates is<br />

generally a weak policy which strongly relies on the accompanying presence <strong>of</strong> a<br />

disposal tax as an incentive to recycle. Soderholm (2001) cites Ecotec (2001) who<br />

find that disposal taxes generally provide a much stronger economic incentive than<br />

the tax on aggregates. Recycling would therefore be an expected consequence <strong>of</strong><br />

wanting to avoid disposal costs (evidence from Denmark exemplifies this point). In<br />

other words, the shift in the market is likely to be more supply driven than demand<br />

driven, but demand can be strengthened through use <strong>of</strong> standards and other<br />

demand-side measures, and this may become more necessary as supply increases.<br />

Figure 46-1 shows the percentage <strong>of</strong> the market accounted for by recycled aggregate<br />

over time, during the introduction <strong>of</strong> both the landfill tax and the tax on aggregates in<br />

the UK.<br />

793 ECOTEC Research and Consulting (2001) Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the Use <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental Taxes and Charges in the EU and its Member States, Accessed 21 st October 2008,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/enveco/taxation/pdf/ch11_aggregated_taxes.pdf<br />

794 D. Legg (2007) Presentation: Evaluation <strong>of</strong> Aggregate Taxes, European Environment Agency.<br />

795 European Environment Agency (2008) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Environmental Taxes and Charges for<br />

Managing Sand, Gravel and Rock Extraction in Selected EU Countries, Accessed 23 rd October 2008,<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/eea_report_2008_2/en/Effectiveness_<strong>of</strong>_environmental_taxes_final_lo<br />

w.pdf<br />

658<br />

29/09/09


The intention to implement a landfill tax was announced in 1994 and this is<br />

seemingly the beginning in a sharp rise in market share <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate, before<br />

the introduction in 1996. The impact <strong>of</strong> the tax on aggregate is less noticeable, but a<br />

slightly sharper increase in recycled aggregate market share can be noticed in line<br />

with the introduction <strong>of</strong> the tax. Broadly speaking, the impacts that the two taxes have<br />

had on production <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate are relative to the level at which the tax has<br />

been set therefore reinforcing the argument that the landfill tax is the driving force<br />

behind increased recycling rates for aggregate.<br />

Figure 46-1: Effects <strong>of</strong> Landfill Tax and Aggregate Levy Introduction in the UK<br />

£/tonne<br />

659<br />

35<br />

30<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

Introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill tax<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

2008<br />

Year<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

tax on aggregate<br />

30<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

%<br />

Landfill Tax (£/tonne)<br />

Aggregate Tax (£/tonne)<br />

Recycled Aggregates as a % <strong>of</strong><br />

the Total Aggregates (%)<br />

Implementation <strong>of</strong> a tax on aggregate policy as part <strong>of</strong> a package which includes a<br />

disposal tax is very important, despite the difficulties involved with attributing any<br />

positive outcome to a specific measure. There appear to be no examples where<br />

aggregates tax have been shown, in the literature, to single-handedly impact upon the<br />

recycling rate <strong>of</strong> C&D waste in a significant manner. This is likely to be a reflection <strong>of</strong>:<br />

� The low levels at which the tax is set, as a percentage <strong>of</strong> the product price; and<br />

� Low elasticities where implemented.<br />

In light <strong>of</strong> this it is possible to see a situation where aggregate tax could be influential,<br />

without an underpinning disposal tax. However, raising the level <strong>of</strong> aggregate tax<br />

could result in the level <strong>of</strong> tax being equal to or greater then the value <strong>of</strong> the product<br />

which policy makers are likely to be tentative about.<br />

Secondly, at the margin, to the extent that primary aggregate consumption is reduced,<br />

the extent <strong>of</strong> quarrying operations may also be reduced. This implies that the<br />

associated environmental costs are tackled, for example, the effect on local<br />

biodiversity and communities though noise, dust and visual intrusion.


46.6 Implementation Costs<br />

The compliance costs for the UK are estimated in a Regulatory Impact Assessment<br />

which was undertaken prior to implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax. It divided the costs into<br />

start-up costs and continuing costs as listed below:<br />

660<br />

� Start-up costs include:<br />

29/09/09<br />

• time to plan and prepare for the new tax<br />

• make changes to administrative and computer systems to account for<br />

the tax;<br />

• staff training; and<br />

• consequential printing costs.<br />

These were thought to range between £750 for small businesses to £50,000 for<br />

large businesses and up to £100,000 for large businesses with multi-site operations.<br />

� Continuing costs include:<br />

• maintaining records for Customs;<br />

• completion <strong>of</strong> 4 tax returns per year; and<br />

• dealing with visits from Customs <strong>of</strong>ficers.<br />

These were estimated to range from £1,500 per annum for small businesses and up<br />

to £10,000 per annum for larger players. 796<br />

The administration cost <strong>of</strong> the tax varies considerably depending on how it is<br />

implemented. For example, in the UK the administrative cost <strong>of</strong> the tax on aggregate<br />

costs Customs and Excise €1.5 million per year (0.33% <strong>of</strong> total revenue raised), and<br />

in Sweden it costs €0.38 (1.7% <strong>of</strong> total revenue raised) million per year. 797<br />

46.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

A direct result <strong>of</strong> implementing the policy is improvement <strong>of</strong> measurements and<br />

monitoring systems regarding primary aggregate extraction because measurement <strong>of</strong><br />

extraction is an essential part <strong>of</strong> the mechanism through which the tax is levied.<br />

The EEA report (2008) describes how in the UK the increasing use <strong>of</strong> recycled<br />

aggregate material has encouraged aggregate producers and those in the<br />

construction and demolition industry to diversify into the recycling market. In turn this<br />

796 HM Customs & Excise Consultation (1998) Aggregates Levy Regulatory Impact Assessment,<br />

Accessed 16 th February 2009,<br />

http://customs.hmrc.gov.uk/channelsPortalWebApp/downloadFile?contentID=HMCE_CL_001429<br />

797 European Environment Agency (2008) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Environmental Taxes and Charges for<br />

Managing Sand, Gravel and Rock Extraction in Selected EU Countries, Accessed 23 rd October 2008,<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/eea_report_2008_2/en/Effectiveness_<strong>of</strong>_environmental_taxes_final_lo<br />

w.pdf


has encouraged innovation in recycling techniques, improving the product range <strong>of</strong><br />

recycled aggregates.<br />

Each year a fixed sum <strong>of</strong> £35 million is diverted to the Aggregate Levy Sustainability<br />

Fund (ALSF). This is out <strong>of</strong> a total revenue <strong>of</strong> €454, which as reported by the EEA<br />

(2008). The ALSF has, amongst other things, funded research by the <strong>Waste</strong> and<br />

Resources Action Plan (WRAP), which led to the establishment <strong>of</strong> an aggregates<br />

forum. Achievements to date are as follows:<br />

661<br />

� improved quality standards for aggregate that is recycled from waste. WRAP<br />

developed the <strong>Waste</strong> Quality Protocol which has significantly lowered barriers,<br />

such as stigma, attached to using aggregates derived from waste materials<br />

and encouraged the expansion <strong>of</strong> demand for secondary aggregates and other<br />

substitute recycled materials;<br />

� raising awareness and increasing end user confidence by organising seminars<br />

to encourage local authorities to use recycled aggregate materials in local<br />

infrastructure projects;<br />

� providing cheap access to capital for reprocessing infrastructure to increase<br />

quality <strong>of</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> substitute aggregates from recycled materials;<br />

� delivering accessible robust information, e.g. Aggregain web-based information<br />

service (www.aggregain.org.uk ), which has over 260 registered users.<br />

46.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

46.8.1 Social Consequences<br />

Anecdotally, a rise in the cost <strong>of</strong> aggregate due to a tax could affect first-time buyers<br />

looking to buy new builds, where the increased cost in aggregate is reflected in the<br />

sale price <strong>of</strong> the property. Those with lower incomes are thought to be far less<br />

affected because they are more likely to be renting property or in social housing.<br />

It is possible that the implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax could disproportionately affect<br />

smaller companies, which in the worst case could lead to closures. This will result in a<br />

more sparsely populated network <strong>of</strong> quarries and distributional consequences<br />

relating to the distance from the quarry due to the high transportation costs and<br />

environmental impacts associated with aggregate transportation. 798<br />

In Sweden when the tax was first implemented in 1996 it was kept low so as to<br />

reduce economic pressure on smaller gravel pits. There was initially some concern<br />

that a higher level <strong>of</strong> tax would cause closure <strong>of</strong> small pits which contained gravel<br />

reserves that had not been fully exploited. As such the effect <strong>of</strong> the tax was thought to<br />

provide both and informative and incentive effect. However, in 2003 the tax was<br />

raised in order to further strengthen the incentive for material substitution 799.<br />

798 British Aggregates Association (2002) Briefing Note on the Quarrying Industry and the Aggregates<br />

Levy, Accessed 5 th January 2009, http://www.british-aggregates.co.uk/documentation/doc13.pdf<br />

799 P. Soderholm (2006) Environmental Taxation in the Natural Resource Extraction Sector: Is it is good<br />

idea? European Environment 16, 232 – 245.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The impact <strong>of</strong> the tax was unevenly distributed throughout the country. In the South <strong>of</strong><br />

the country, where natural gravel is scarce, natural gravel deposits were maintained<br />

therefore the tax achieved its main goal. However, in the North <strong>of</strong> the country, where<br />

natural gravel is more abundant, costs were greatly increased. The overall effect was<br />

unfair to those in the North and had a distorting effect on the market.<br />

Introduction <strong>of</strong> a tax must always be preceded by consideration <strong>of</strong> the elasticity <strong>of</strong><br />

demand <strong>of</strong> the product. Aggregate is usually priced at a low rate, but is an expensive<br />

material to transport over any great distance. The higher the level <strong>of</strong> tax the greater<br />

the likelihood <strong>of</strong> material being imported from areas where there is no tax. For<br />

example, in the UK trade distortions between Northern Ireland, where a reduced rate<br />

<strong>of</strong> the tax on aggregates does apply, and Ireland, where there is no tax on aggregates,<br />

have been identified. Coordination across country boundaries would reduce the risk<br />

<strong>of</strong> this occurring across country borders. 800 Alternatively, if possible, implementation<br />

<strong>of</strong> border tax adjustments may be feasible but probably only possible at the border <strong>of</strong><br />

the EU.<br />

46.9 Complementary Policies<br />

In general terms the tax on aggregates works in conjunction with varying types <strong>of</strong><br />

policy throughout the various stages <strong>of</strong> aggregate use, beginning with extraction all<br />

the way through to disposal.<br />

662<br />

1. At the aggregate extraction stage permit rules work alongside the tax on<br />

aggregates;<br />

2. At the end-use stage, road building standards and material standards (see<br />

Section 47.0 for aggregate standards) work in conjunction with the tax on<br />

aggregates. Public procurement rules could also influence demand for<br />

secondary materials through specifying their use, or using an evaluation<br />

method for tenders which rewards bidders making use <strong>of</strong> secondary<br />

aggregates. Finally, it might be possible to incentivise secondary aggregate<br />

use in specific projects (see below), though this would seem to be a less<br />

efficient way <strong>of</strong> addressing the matter;<br />

3. At the aggregate disposal stage, landfill taxes strengthen the economic<br />

viability <strong>of</strong> recycling so working to achieve the same goal as the tax on<br />

aggregates. In addition, policies which prevent ‘sham recovery’ <strong>of</strong> demolition<br />

materials will help improve the prospects for recycling <strong>of</strong> aggregates.<br />

800 European Environment Agency (2008) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Environmental Taxes and Charges for<br />

Managing Sand, Gravel and Rock Extraction in Selected EU Countries, Accessed 23 rd October 2008,<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/eea_report_2008_2/en/Effectiveness_<strong>of</strong>_environmental_taxes_final_lo<br />

w.pdf<br />

29/09/09


46.9.1 Quality Standards<br />

European Standards for Aggregates, which are derived from natural, recycled and<br />

manufactured materials, were introduced in 2004. 801 They facilitate the use <strong>of</strong><br />

recycled aggregate by increasing confidence in the quality and consistent nature <strong>of</strong><br />

the product. In support <strong>of</strong> this, WRAP funded a programme <strong>of</strong> work in the UK which<br />

provides guidance for producers <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate. 802<br />

In Sweden the National Roads Administration (NRA) has been raising standards in<br />

road quality since 1994. In order to cope with the frost, thick roads are needed and<br />

crushed rock was found to withstand these conditions far better than gravel. In light<br />

<strong>of</strong> this, the NRA supported road construction companies that were proposing to use<br />

secondary crushed rock. It is difficult to measure the impact <strong>of</strong> the NRA’s road<br />

standards compared to the gravel tax since the effect <strong>of</strong> one could be obscuring the<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> the other (see Section 47.0 for aggregate standards).<br />

46.9.2 <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Tax<br />

In Denmark the raw material tax was implemented in conjunction with a waste<br />

disposal tax, the key aim being that the combination <strong>of</strong> the taxes would reduce use <strong>of</strong><br />

resources and encourage substitution <strong>of</strong> recycled materials. The effects <strong>of</strong> the raw<br />

material tax therefore must be considered in conjunction with the waste tax.<br />

In 1996 a fixed charge on excavation and dredging was applied to raw materials. The<br />

revenue from this fund was intended to fund research into alternative construction<br />

materials within the industry – but this has not yet happened.<br />

As previously discussed in Section 46.5, a landfill tax is in place in both Sweden and<br />

the UK which is likely to encourage aggregate recycling at the disposal stage, but<br />

quantifying the direct impact upon aggregate recycling from both taxes is complex. It<br />

is expected though that in both the UK and Sweden landfill tax does work in<br />

conjunction with the tax on aggregates because the landfill tax provides an incentive<br />

to re-use material at the end <strong>of</strong> life. In light <strong>of</strong> this, waste from the C&D sector is being<br />

used as an aggregate resource to avoid both landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste, and the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

extracting new material, made higher by the tax on aggregates.<br />

46.9.3 Incentives<br />

The Netherlands Government incentivises the use <strong>of</strong> secondary aggregate, to<br />

discourage the use <strong>of</strong> virgin materials, when construction projects for the public<br />

sector are being undertaken. 803<br />

801 WRAP (2008) European Standards for Aggregates (2004), Accessed 23 rd October 2008,<br />

http://www.aggregain.org.uk/quality/aggregates_standards/european.html<br />

802 WRAP (2005) The Quality Protocol for the Production <strong>of</strong> Aggregates from Inert <strong>Waste</strong>, Accessed<br />

October 23 rd 2008, http://www.wrap.org.uk/downloads/0083_Quality_Protocol_A4.21d89729.87.pdf<br />

803 AEA Technology (2007) <strong>International</strong> Approaches to <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Minimisation, Final<br />

Report for Defra (BREW), Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

663<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


46.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

A tax on aggregates should encourage use <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate by shifting demand<br />

in favour <strong>of</strong> secondary materials, and reducing demand for virgin materials.<br />

Influencing the behaviour <strong>of</strong> supply and demand relies on the elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand in<br />

the market. However, the following three points suggest that the supply and demand<br />

may be intrinsically more inelastic due to:<br />

664<br />

1. the lead time required on obtaining new sources <strong>of</strong> aggregate can be up to 4<br />

years, in which time the price will rapidly rise until availability improves;<br />

2. aggregate suppliers do not account for the rush on material when it does<br />

become available by curbing sales in order to even out demand; and<br />

3. the aggregate production sector will be greatly influenced by a recession due<br />

to their close ties with the housing and construction industry. 804<br />

The extent to which the tax has the ability to change the pricing structure between<br />

virgin and secondary material depends upon the level at which they are set. In<br />

principle, the efficient tax rate is that which internalises the externalities associated<br />

with primary aggregates extraction. However, from the perspective <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

efficiency, externalities associated with secondary aggregates preparation should also<br />

be taxed.<br />

Notwithstanding the theoretical principles, few countries have sought to set the level<br />

<strong>of</strong> taxes on aggregates through reference to some measurement <strong>of</strong> the externalities<br />

associated with aggregates extraction. The UK provides an exception, the level <strong>of</strong> the<br />

tax being based upon a study that estimated the total external costs <strong>of</strong> aggregate<br />

extraction as €380 million per year which is comparable to the current levels <strong>of</strong><br />

revenue from the tax <strong>of</strong> €428. 805<br />

46.11 Enforcement<br />

As a tax or levy, the enforcement is undertaken by central government departments<br />

and lack <strong>of</strong> compliance can result in court action. The enforcement procedure for the<br />

UK includes initial auditing to identify potential businesses which may not be<br />

complying, and as such, their audit frequency greatly increases. Following this, failure<br />

to comply can lead to financial penalties which include:<br />

� if one fails to register at the correct time they may be liable to a £250 penalty<br />

or 5% <strong>of</strong> the levy involved, whichever is greater;<br />

http://www.crwplatform.co.uk/conwaste/assets/Publications/2006-7-Reports/<strong>International</strong>-<br />

Approaches-to-<strong>Waste</strong>-Prevention-and-Minimisation.pdf<br />

804 R. Bleischwitz and B. Bahn-Walkowiak (2006) Sustainable Development in the European<br />

Aggregates Industry, Wuppertal Institute for Climate, Environment and Energy, Accessed 20 th January<br />

2009, http://web.fu-berlin.de/ffu/akumwelt/bc2006/papers/Bleischwitz_Bahn-W_Aggregates.pdf<br />

805 Converted using an exchange rate <strong>of</strong> €1.2 = £1.<br />

29/09/09


665<br />

� if one fails to deregister, comply with regulations, produce records and<br />

information, or render returns or full payment on time they may be subject to a<br />

£250 penalty;<br />

� if one is a non-resident tax payer and fails to obtain Customs’ approval to<br />

appoint a tax representative they may be subject to a £10,000 penalty;<br />

� if discovered that one had under-declared or over-claimed credit on the return<br />

they may be liable to pay a penalty equal to 5% <strong>of</strong> the amount <strong>of</strong> levy underdeclared<br />

or over-declared;<br />

� if one is an unregistered customer and a genuine error resulting in an under<br />

declaration by the registered supplier results, one may be liable to a penalty <strong>of</strong><br />

105% <strong>of</strong> the value <strong>of</strong> the levy; or<br />

� if one evades the levy, one takes or omit to take any action, and the conduct<br />

involves dishonesty, one will render themselves liable to a penalty equal to the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> levy evaded or sought to be evaded plus the actual amount <strong>of</strong> levy<br />

evaded’. 806<br />

In Denmark possible sanctions are fines and ultimately withdrawal <strong>of</strong> registration<br />

which would result in immediate termination <strong>of</strong> trading rights. It is also thought that<br />

the success <strong>of</strong> the system is due to an element <strong>of</strong> self-discipline where those who are<br />

found to have evaded the policy are considered negatively by the general public. 807<br />

46.12 Lessons Learned<br />

When designing the policy, consideration has to be given as to the price differential to<br />

be established. Few countries have based this on environmental damages, though<br />

such an assessment is less than straightforward where aggregates are concerned. 808<br />

In the Czech Republic (where the tax was not introduced with respect to waste) the<br />

tax on aggregates was introduced at a low level creating very little price differential<br />

between virgin and recycled aggregate. As a result, as might have been anticipated,<br />

there has been very limited impact upon behaviour, and hence, recycling rates. 809<br />

806 Sonnevera <strong>International</strong> Corporation (2006) Construction, Renovation and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Materials: Opportunities for <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction and Diversion,<br />

http://environment.gov.ab.ca/info/library/7703.pdf<br />

807 Danish Environmental Protection Agency (1999) Economic Instruments in Environmental Protection<br />

in Denmark.<br />

808 The experience <strong>of</strong> the UK in this context was that a contingent valuation study was undertaken<br />

which was re-done, and then criticised by some well known environmental economists for failing to<br />

understand, for example, the difference between marginal and total impacts. It can be argued that the<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> reducing aggregates extraction are, at the margin, likely to be rather small because much <strong>of</strong><br />

the externality caused is associated with the disamenity <strong>of</strong> ‘the quarry’ rather than the impact <strong>of</strong> the<br />

marginal tonne.<br />

809 European Environment Agency (2008) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Environmental Taxes and Charges for<br />

Managing Sand, Gravel and Rock Extraction in Selected EU Countries, Accessed 23 rd October 2008,<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


A lesson from the case in Ireland (as explained in Section 46.2.1.2) is that a tax must<br />

be considered in respect <strong>of</strong> bordering countries in order to avoid illegal trade in<br />

aggregate materials.<br />

46.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

The Danish Ministry <strong>of</strong> Taxation were monitoring levels <strong>of</strong> raw material extraction prior<br />

to the implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax. This is not a pre-requisite as such, but if such a<br />

system were in place already, then implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax would be a more<br />

straight-forward process. In addition, a meaningful assessment <strong>of</strong> the policy’s impact<br />

is made much more straightforward (arguably without this, evaluation is not possible).<br />

666<br />

29/09/09


47.0 Product Standards for Aggregates -<br />

<strong>International</strong><br />

47.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Product standards ensure that recycled materials meet minimum quality<br />

requirements. For aggregates these requirements are in relation to environmental<br />

and engineering safety standards. The introduction <strong>of</strong> product standards increases<br />

confidence in secondary materials through certification <strong>of</strong> the recycled product. It is<br />

more common for non-legislative standards to have been introduced. However,<br />

several examples are given where standards have been mandated at either a<br />

national or regional level.<br />

47.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

In 1998 Mandate 125 introduced European standards for aggregates related to their<br />

end-uses, under the Construction Products Directive (89/106/EEC). This meant that<br />

aggregate types were assigned a standard reference.<br />

Following this European Standards for Aggregates were introduced in 2004. They<br />

include a grading classification system and categories which are used to describe<br />

performance. They are applicable to natural, recycled and manufactured aggregate.<br />

The system involves use <strong>of</strong> a CE marking system, which is an easily recognisable<br />

symbol <strong>of</strong> quality. Although this legislation is in place and is valid across all EU<br />

countries, it is not mandatory is most countries. However, voluntary use <strong>of</strong> the system<br />

could be beneficial to secondary aggregate markets. 810<br />

The following countries have mandated standards for aggregate using the European<br />

Standards for Aggregates framework, and the CE marking:<br />

667<br />

� Austria;<br />

� Belgium (Wallonia);<br />

� Czech Republic;<br />

� France;<br />

� Italy;<br />

� The Netherlands;<br />

� Poland;<br />

� Slovakia; and<br />

810 WRAP (2004) European Standards for Aggregates, Accessed 21 st January 2009,<br />

http://www.aggregain.org.uk/quality/aggregates_standards/european.html<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


668<br />

� Spain. 811<br />

Voluntary standards apply across many countries, including:<br />

� Australia, where the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment and Heritage have<br />

developed a recycling guide for aggregates in partnership with several<br />

stakeholder groups. As a result <strong>of</strong> this publication state governments have<br />

produced similar guides.<br />

� Belgium (Flanders) for recycled aggregates;<br />

� Denmark, where the Danish Society <strong>of</strong> Civil Engineers has set up a standard<br />

for the use <strong>of</strong> crushed concrete and stones as an aggregate material in new<br />

concrete;<br />

� Germany, for recycled materials as aggregates in concrete, recycled aggregate<br />

and recycled soil; development <strong>of</strong> ‘RAW’ standards<br />

� Sweden, where the National Roads Administration (NRA) has been raising<br />

standards in road quality since 1994. In order to cope with the frost, thick<br />

roads are needed and crushed rock was found to withstand these conditions<br />

far better than gravel. In light <strong>of</strong> this, the NRA supported road construction<br />

companies that were proposing to use secondary crushed rock;<br />

� UK, where a Quality Protocol for Aggregates has been developed by WRAP in<br />

partnership with the Quarry Products Association, the Highways Agency and<br />

the Environment Agency.<br />

47.2.1 Country-specific Characteristics<br />

There is a lack <strong>of</strong> evaluation studies and reviews regarding this policy. The majority <strong>of</strong><br />

information throughout this report therefore either relates specifically to the<br />

Netherlands, or to the European standards in general. Additional information is added<br />

where possible.<br />

The Netherlands<br />

The Dutch Building Material Decree came into effect in 1999. It was introduced to<br />

overcome barriers to reusing waste materials in construction. At the time there was<br />

concern with regards to the impact <strong>of</strong> primary and secondary building materials upon<br />

soil and surface water.<br />

It applies to stony materials and earth in construction and aims to:<br />

� restrict pollution <strong>of</strong> soil and surface waters due to leaching; and<br />

� reduce the use <strong>of</strong> primary raw materials. 812<br />

811 Union Europeenne des Producteurs de Granulats (UEPG) (2005) UEPG Statement on CE Marking<br />

and European Aggregates Standards, Accessed 20 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.asfaltskolan.se/metoddag_05/MET05pdf/UEPG%20Statement%20on%20ce%20Marking<br />

%20and%20European%20Aggregates%20Standards-%20February%202005.pdf<br />

29/09/09


It lays down regulations and standards, applicable to primary and secondary<br />

materials, which ensure quality standards are met. The final products are certified in<br />

order to provide increased levels <strong>of</strong> confidence in the recycled materials.<br />

Belgium and the Czech Republic<br />

In Belgium and the Czech Republic introduction <strong>of</strong> the standards has been specifically<br />

in relation to aggregate standards for road construction only.<br />

UK<br />

As an example <strong>of</strong> voluntary implementation <strong>of</strong> aggregate standards, in the UK those<br />

waste re-processing facilities accepting recycled aggregate and wishing to abide by<br />

the standards are key to the process implementation. Testing <strong>of</strong> the material must be<br />

undertaken and records <strong>of</strong> the output kept. Upon delivery <strong>of</strong> the aggregate, a quality<br />

statement will state that the product conforms to the protocol and if required<br />

evidence including test results, test procedures and outline details <strong>of</strong> the factory<br />

production control manual should be supplied.<br />

47.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The Netherlands<br />

Those involved in the construction process will all have to be aware, and abide by, the<br />

material standards set in the Building Materials Decree. This includes contractors,<br />

individuals, manufacturers and suppliers <strong>of</strong> building materials and laboratories<br />

employed to test the material quality.<br />

UK<br />

As a voluntary measure in the UK WRAP and the QPA have been central to driving<br />

forward the implementation <strong>of</strong> aggregate standards within industry. This has involved<br />

awareness raising through production <strong>of</strong> documentation available on their websites,<br />

including checklists for producers and purchasers. WRAP have run several free ‘Good<br />

Practice’ workshops for producers and purchasers in order to provide advice and<br />

training.<br />

Producers <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate are responsible for implementation <strong>of</strong> the quality<br />

standard within their facility. Awareness amongst purchasers is also important,<br />

especially where standards are voluntary.<br />

47.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

The following study highlights the pre-implementation discussions regarding the likely<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> the policy. There was concern that due to the blanket application <strong>of</strong><br />

standards that were applicable to primary and secondary materials, the use <strong>of</strong><br />

812 Netherlands Ministry <strong>of</strong> Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment (1999) Building Materials<br />

Decree Text and Explanatory Notes, Accessed 22 nd January 2009,<br />

http://www.sharedspaces.nl/docs/internationaal/BMDtexts.pdf<br />

669<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


secondary materials may suffer in the short-term. This line <strong>of</strong> thinking was attributed<br />

to the ease at which the different sources <strong>of</strong> aggregate would reach the required<br />

standards, assuming it would be more straightforward for primary aggregate.<br />

670<br />

� OECD & Dutch Working Party on National Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> (2002) Case<br />

Studies on <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments for Environmentally Sustainable Buildings,<br />

www.olis.oecd.org/olis/2001doc.nsf/LinkTo/NT00000C46/$FILE/JT0012820<br />

2.PDF Accessed 21st January 2009.<br />

� S. Böhmer, G. Moser, C. Neubauer, M. Peltoniemi, E. Schachermayer, M.<br />

Tesar, B. Walter & B. Winter (2008) Aggregates Case Study, Report to the<br />

Institute for Prospective Technological Studies (part <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Commission’s Joint Research Centre).<br />

The Quarry Products Association, WRAP and the Highways Agency have been at the<br />

centre <strong>of</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> the voluntary standards in the UK. The following reports<br />

and websites highlight these key sources:<br />

� WRAP (2004) European Standards for Aggregates, Accessed 21st January<br />

2009,<br />

http://www.aggregain.org.uk/quality/aggregates_standards/european.html<br />

� WRAP’s Aggregate Programme website,<br />

http://www.aggregain.org.uk/wrap_aggregates/index.html, accessed 16 th<br />

February 2009.<br />

� QPA’s website, http://www.qpa.org/prod_agg01.htm, accessed 16 th February<br />

2009.<br />

47.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

Creating standards for aggregates aims to ensure that recycled aggregate can be<br />

competitive with primary aggregate. Certification aims to break down negative<br />

perceptions regarding the standard <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate. An increased market share<br />

<strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate means the demand for aggregate recycling increases, which<br />

results in less going to final disposal facilities. Also, the harmful effects <strong>of</strong><br />

transportation may be reduced where recycled aggregate is consumed within the<br />

locality <strong>of</strong> where it is produced. As shown in Section 46.0, the supply <strong>of</strong> material may<br />

be expected to grow in the wake <strong>of</strong> combined aggregate tax/disposal tax policies.<br />

All <strong>of</strong> the countries listed with mandatory aggregate product standards have disposal<br />

taxes or bans in place. It is thought that the importance <strong>of</strong> product standards may be<br />

more prominent in their effect if introduced to countries without such taxes in place.<br />

European Standards<br />

Application <strong>of</strong> one standard to aggregates, irrespective <strong>of</strong> their source, enables<br />

secondary aggregate to compete to higher grade applications, which in turn is likely to<br />

increase their market share.<br />

The Netherlands<br />

The Netherlands has achieved diversion rates <strong>of</strong> more than 95% <strong>of</strong> C&D waste from<br />

landfill and final disposal. However, despite the introduction <strong>of</strong> quality standards it<br />

29/09/09


has been recognised that recycled or reused aggregate is <strong>of</strong>ten used in low grade<br />

applications as a result <strong>of</strong> poor sorting. 813<br />

47.6 Implementation Costs<br />

The review undertaken by the Dutch Working Party on National Environmental <strong>Policy</strong><br />

was unable to identify exact administrative costs <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> the policy.<br />

However, it was recognised that cost was likely to be more significant at the beginning<br />

<strong>of</strong> the supply chain. The policy requires pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> quality to be submitted to local<br />

authorities by owners <strong>of</strong> the project which should be provided to them by the<br />

contractor, who in turn should receive them from the manufacturer.<br />

47.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The introduction <strong>of</strong> quality standards for recycled aggregate is a relatively new<br />

initiative, and as shown above, has infrequently been implemented as a policy. It has<br />

become feasible to introduce this as a policy due to the advanced aggregate testing<br />

technologies that have been developed, e.g. laboratory testing to assess the size and<br />

shape <strong>of</strong> aggregate particles. 814<br />

It is thought that the development <strong>of</strong> such standards is an innovative approach which<br />

can be complementary to, as well as <strong>of</strong>fering a (weaker) alternative to, more<br />

established policies such as waste disposal taxes, aggregate taxes, and bans. 815<br />

47.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

The main aim <strong>of</strong> the introduction <strong>of</strong> aggregate standards is to reduce stigma attached<br />

to the recycled product, therefore encourage increased use. In principle, this should<br />

take place at the expense <strong>of</strong> primary aggregates, so that the primary industry would<br />

be expected to be affected if the policy is successful.<br />

Reports reviewed have not highlighted any specific distributional issues as a direct<br />

result <strong>of</strong> the policy (and the differing implementation).<br />

47.9 Complementary Policies<br />

Aggregate quality standards are considered to be at the end <strong>of</strong> a chain <strong>of</strong> policies<br />

effective within the C&D sector. They work to increase confidence in aggregates<br />

813 AEA Technology (2007) <strong>International</strong> Approaches to <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Minimisation, Final<br />

Report for Defra (BREW), Accessed 15th October 2008,<br />

http://www.crwplatform.co.uk/conwaste/assets/Publications/2006-7-Reports/<strong>International</strong>-<br />

Approaches-to-<strong>Waste</strong>-Prevention-and-Minimisation.pdf<br />

814 B. Schouenborg and A. Akesson (2004) Aggregate Research in Support <strong>of</strong> European Standardisation,<br />

Accessed 21 st January 2009,<br />

http://www.springerlink.com/content/2ul0qchmepkkbffh/fulltext.pdf?page=1<br />

815 OECD & Dutch Working Party on National Environmental <strong>Policy</strong> (2002) Case Studies on <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments for<br />

Environmentally Sustainable Buildings, Accessed 21 st January 2009,<br />

http://www.olis.oecd.org/olis/2001doc.nsf/LinkTo/NT00000C46/$FILE/JT00128202.PDF<br />

671<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


derived from waste materials and aim to encourage the demand for secondary<br />

aggregates. This alone would be unlikely to be effective at increasing the market<br />

share <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate, and strongly relies on fiscal measures such as the<br />

landfill tax and tax on aggregates, in order to have an impact through encouraging the<br />

supply <strong>of</strong> the material and demand for it.<br />

47.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

Due to a lack <strong>of</strong> evidence this can only be answered speculatively. It is thought that<br />

ensuring standards are the same across all types <strong>of</strong> aggregates will encourage a shift<br />

towards greater use <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate. This is because the price which recycled<br />

aggregate can attract in the market will no longer be so heavily discounted relative to<br />

primary material (since it would be considered as being <strong>of</strong> an equivalent standard to<br />

primary aggregate). This economic assessment makes the assumption that the social<br />

stigma associated with recycled aggregate is removed by introduction <strong>of</strong> the product<br />

standard.<br />

47.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

At this relatively early stage implementing product standards as a policy there is very<br />

little information regarding enforcement, and any potential action that may be taken if<br />

non-compliance is detected. It is only known that, as is the case in the Netherlands, it<br />

is most likely to be local authorities who are responsible for enforcement <strong>of</strong> the<br />

standards.<br />

47.12 Lessons Learned<br />

Going forward, the <strong>International</strong> Recycling Federation is striving towards harmonising<br />

quality standards for recycled materials. There are varying levels <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

product standards throughout the countries mentioned, many <strong>of</strong> which are purely<br />

voluntary initiatives. However, there seems to considerable support from industry<br />

which ought to help to drive forward the standards onto a firmer, statutory footing.<br />

672<br />

29/09/09


48.0 Minimum Recycling Standards<br />

(Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>) - <strong>International</strong><br />

48.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

A number <strong>of</strong> countries currently employ a minimum recycling standards policy for<br />

householders, commerce and industry, and construction and demolition wastes. This<br />

section presents those minimum standards for the construction and demolition (C&D)<br />

waste stream. These policies require the separate collection <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

materials, with the key goals <strong>of</strong> diverting waste away from landfill and increasing<br />

material recovery.<br />

As noted in Annex 1.0, the revised <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive now requires C&D<br />

waste to meet 70% recycling targets:<br />

673<br />

2. In order to comply with the objectives <strong>of</strong> this Directive, and to move towards<br />

a European recycling society with a high level <strong>of</strong> resource efficiency, Member<br />

States shall take the necessary measures designed to achieve the following<br />

targets:<br />

a) by 2020 the preparing for re-use and the recycling <strong>of</strong> waste materials such as at<br />

least paper, metal, plastic and glass from households and possibly from other<br />

origins as far as these waste streams are similar to waste from households,<br />

shall be increased to a minimum <strong>of</strong> overall 50% by weight;<br />

b) by 2020 the preparing for re-use, recycling and other material recovery,<br />

including backfilling operations using waste to substitute other materials, <strong>of</strong><br />

non-hazardous construction and demolition waste excluding naturally occurring<br />

material defined in category 17 05 04 in the European <strong>Waste</strong> Catalogue (EWC)<br />

shall be increased to a minimum <strong>of</strong> 70% by weight.<br />

The use <strong>of</strong> minimum recycling standards is generally designed to improve resource<br />

recovery from the C&D sector and to reduce waste sent to landfill.<br />

48.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

The countries that currently use a mandatory minimum recycling standard for the<br />

C&D sector include Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Slovenia, the<br />

Netherlands, USA and Japan. A minimum recycling standard for C&D has been<br />

implemented in these countries in order to push waste up the hierarchy away from<br />

landfill, and to increase the recovery <strong>of</strong> materials and hence reduce the need for<br />

primary material consumption.<br />

The main country-specific policy details are discussed below.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


48.2.1 Austria<br />

Under the Ordinance on the Separation <strong>of</strong> Materials Accumulated during Construction<br />

Work (Federal Law Gazette no. 259/1991), C&D companies are obliged to separate<br />

their waste into groups <strong>of</strong> materials (mineral construction waste, excavated soil,<br />

concrete waste, broken asphalt, wood, metal and plastic waste, as well as<br />

construction site waste) if they exceed certain threshold levels as shown in Table<br />

48-1.<br />

Table 48-1: Threshold Quantities for Mandatory Separation & Recovery in Austria<br />

674<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Fraction Fraction<br />

Threshold Threshold Quantities Quantities (tonnes)<br />

(tonnes)<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>of</strong> mineral origin 40<br />

Excavated soil 20<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> concrete 20<br />

Non separated C&D<br />

waste<br />

Road construction waste 5<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> wood 5<br />

Plastic waste 2<br />

Scrap metal 2<br />

29/09/09<br />

10<br />

Source: C. Pladerer (2006) ‘Towards Sustainable Plastic Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> in Europe’ Initiatives for a Sustainable Plastic C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in Europe; The<br />

Case <strong>of</strong> Austria, Presentation by the Okologie Institut for the European Workshop – Brussels, 24 th April<br />

2006.<br />

48.2.2 Germany<br />

The Ordinance on the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>s <strong>of</strong> Commercial Origin and<br />

Certain Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>s (Commercial <strong>Waste</strong>s Ordinance) came in<br />

effect from 1 st January 2003. This stipulated the separate collection <strong>of</strong> C&D waste<br />

where the waste had been produced separately for the following materials:<br />

� glass;<br />

� plastic;<br />

� metals; and<br />

� concrete.


Companies are obliged to either separate their own waste and have it collected or<br />

commit their waste to special commercial waste sorting facilities. 816 Where on-site<br />

separation is not possible, due to technical or economical constraints, mixed site<br />

waste consisting <strong>of</strong> wood, glass, plastic, metal, concrete, bricks, tiles and ceramics<br />

must be sent to pre-treatment facilities which have a recovery rate <strong>of</strong> at least 85%.<br />

Other mixed waste must also be sent to a pre-treatment facility but a recovery rate is<br />

not stipulated.<br />

48.2.3 California, USA<br />

The California Integrated <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board (CIWMB) encourages cities to<br />

adopt a C&D Materials Recycling Ordinance and as a result there are many cities that<br />

have mandated this. An ordinance requires that at least 50% C&D material generated<br />

from a project is reused or recycled, and at least 75% inert material is diverted from<br />

landfill.<br />

The system requires a permit to be applied for, a non-refundable administration fee to<br />

be paid, and a deposit, or bond, to be paid for performance security which is refunded<br />

if the minimum recycling requirements <strong>of</strong> the Ordinance are met. A reporting system<br />

is in place so that checks can be carried out after project completion. The<br />

administration fee is based on 0.3% <strong>of</strong> the project value and the performance security<br />

fee is between 1.5-2% <strong>of</strong> the project value.<br />

Implementation throughout California varies slightly by country, but the mechanism is<br />

broadly the same. Different authorities have different criteria for the projects which<br />

must comply. The City <strong>of</strong> Concord, California, is an example <strong>of</strong> where this policy<br />

mechanism uses project value. Projects which must comply with the Ordinance are:<br />

675<br />

1. a residential or commercial project worth $50,000 or more;<br />

2. a city-owned or sponsored project worth $150,000 or more; and<br />

3. a residential or commercial ro<strong>of</strong>ing/re-ro<strong>of</strong>ing project worth $10,000 or<br />

more. 817<br />

(a more complete list <strong>of</strong> Californian Ordinances can be found on the CIWMB<br />

website). 818<br />

Alternatively authorities can use size <strong>of</strong> the project, as the City <strong>of</strong> Menlo Park,<br />

California has done, where projects <strong>of</strong> the following sizes must comply with the<br />

Ordinance:<br />

816 Federal Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety (2002) Ordinance on<br />

the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>s <strong>of</strong> Commercial Origin and Certain Construction and Demolition<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>s (Commercials <strong>Waste</strong>s Ordinance-CWO), Accessed 30 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.bmu.de/files/pdfs/allgemein/application/pdf/gewerbeabfallv_engl.pdf<br />

817 City <strong>of</strong> Concord (2008) Accessed 24 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.city<strong>of</strong>concord.org/living/recycle/cdordinance.htm<br />

818 California Integrated <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board (2008) Accessed 24 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.ciwmb.ca.gov/ConDemo/SampleDocs/<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


676<br />

1. for residential construction and demolition, projects that are 1,000 square<br />

feet or greater; or<br />

2. for commercial construction and demolition, projects that are 5,000 square<br />

feet or greater. 819<br />

Several cities in California have adopted mandatory recycling ordinances with a<br />

refunded compliance bond based approach which provides an incentive to<br />

successfully reach the targets. In places where recycling mandates apply it is normal<br />

for a permit scheme to be in place – permits must be obtained in order to undertake<br />

the construction/demolition project. Where the refunded compliance bond scheme is<br />

also applied, the bond is paid when the permit is received, and returned, when pro<strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> meeting the mandated recycling standards is received, by the enforcement body.<br />

The size <strong>of</strong> the bond required is calculated in various ways but is usually relative to<br />

the size <strong>of</strong> the construction/demolition project. The following examples from San<br />

Diego, San Jose and San Francisco illustrate this policy mechanism.<br />

48.2.4 San Diego, California, USA<br />

The requirements for recycling and disposal <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition debris<br />

were introduced in San Diego in July 2008. The size <strong>of</strong> the project relates to the size<br />

<strong>of</strong> the bond required as shown in Table 48-2.<br />

Certified Recycling Facilities must be allocated to a project via documentation known<br />

as the ‘<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Form I’ which must be submitted to San Diego’s<br />

Environmental Services <strong>Department</strong> along with the required bond. The overall<br />

recycling rate was set at 50% for the first six months, after which time it will be<br />

increased to 75%. However, this does include a 90% recycling requirement specific to<br />

inert waste. Recycling, reuse and disposal receipts need to be submitted in order to<br />

retrieve the bond alongside a ‘<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Form II’. 820<br />

819 City <strong>of</strong> Menlo Park (2008) Construction and Demolition Debris Recycling and Salvage<br />

Requirements, Accessed 24 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.menlopark.org/departments/bld/condemor.pdf<br />

820 The City <strong>of</strong> San Diego Environmental Services <strong>Department</strong> (2008) Requirements for Recycling and<br />

Disposal <strong>of</strong> Construction and Demolition Debris Information Bulletin 119, Accessed 16 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.sandiego.gov/development-services/industry/pdf/infobulletin/ib119.pdf<br />

29/09/09


Table 48-2: Construction and Demolition Debris Recycling Deposits / Bonds<br />

677<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Deposit/Sq.<br />

Deposit/Sq.<br />

Ft.<br />

Ft.<br />

Mi Minimum Mi<br />

nimum nimum<br />

Sq.Ft.<br />

Sq.Ft.<br />

Maximum<br />

Maximum<br />

Sq.Ft.<br />

Sq.Ft.<br />

Subject Subject to to<br />

to<br />

Deposit Deposit<br />

Deposit<br />

Residential new construction – detached $0.40 500 125,000<br />

Residential new construction - attached $0.40 500 100,000<br />

Non-residential new construction –<br />

commercial<br />

$0.20 1,000 25,000<br />

Non-residential new construction –industrial $0.20 1,000 75,000<br />

Non-residential alterations $0.70 286 No<br />

maximum<br />

Residential demolition $0.70 286 No<br />

maximum<br />

Non-residential demolition $0.20 1,000 No<br />

maximum<br />

Flat Rate<br />

Range Range <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Depos Deposits Depos ts<br />

(bonds)<br />

(bonds)<br />

$200 -<br />

$50,000<br />

$200 -<br />

$40,000<br />

$200 -<br />

$5,00<br />

$200 -<br />

$15,000<br />

$200 and<br />

up<br />

$200 and<br />

up<br />

$200 and<br />

up<br />

Ro<strong>of</strong> project with tear-<strong>of</strong>f -- -- $200<br />

Residential alterations -- -- $1,000<br />

Source: City <strong>of</strong> San Diego Development Services, Information Bulletin 119 August 2008, Requirements<br />

for Recycling and Disposal <strong>of</strong> Construction and Demolition Debris,<br />

http://www.sandiego.gov/development-services/industry/pdf/infobulletin/ib119.pdf<br />

48.2.5 San Francisco, California, USA<br />

San Francisco’s recycling mandate applies only to mixed construction and demolition<br />

waste in order to ensure it gets processed and diverted from landfill as efficiently as<br />

possible. This requires the contractor to have the mixed waste removed from the site<br />

by a Registered Transporter who must deliver the waste to a Registered Facility. A<br />

Registered Facility must be capable <strong>of</strong> recycling 65% <strong>of</strong> mixed C&D waste. Receipt <strong>of</strong>


pro<strong>of</strong> from the Registered Facility that a minimum <strong>of</strong> 65% <strong>of</strong> the waste has been<br />

recycled enables the contractor to receive their bond back. 821<br />

48.2.6 City <strong>of</strong> San Jose, California, USA<br />

San Jose introduced its Construction and Demolition Diversion Deposit (CDDD)<br />

Program in 2001. Projects being undertaken for the city authority and private new<br />

construction, alteration and demolition projects all require a permit. Contractors<br />

running these projects must also pay a deposit which is calculated according to<br />

project size and value. Private permitted projects must comply with 50% recycling<br />

requirements and city authority projects must meet a 75% target in order to receive<br />

their deposit back. Projects that do not require a permit and deposit must still comply<br />

with recycling reporting requirements. Processing facilities receiving C&D waste must<br />

be certified and those receiving source separated recyclate must have a proven<br />

recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 90% or more. 822<br />

48.2.7 City <strong>of</strong> Portland, USA<br />

The City <strong>of</strong> Portland’s Office for Sustainable Development (OSD) implemented<br />

minimum recycling standards for construction and demolition projects which were<br />

effective from 14 th November 2008. Where a construction or demolition project is<br />

valued at $50,000 or more the project contractor is required to recycle at least 75%<br />

<strong>of</strong> the total waste materials produced on site. However, the following materials must<br />

all be recycled:<br />

678<br />

29/09/09<br />

� wood;<br />

� corrugated cardboard;<br />

� metal;<br />

� rubble; and<br />

� land clearing debris.<br />

Containers must be made available to assist with separate collection <strong>of</strong> the above<br />

materials.<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> the policy, contractors must complete Recycling Plan Forms on which the<br />

materials to be recycled must be identified, and the collector for each material. These<br />

are returned to the OSD.<br />

821 City and County <strong>of</strong> San Francisco (2006) Construction and Demolition Debris Recovery Program<br />

Ordinance No.27-06, Accessed 16 th January 2009,<br />

http://sfenvironment.org/downloads/library/canddinformation.pdf<br />

822 Gruzen Samton LLP with City Green Inc. (2003) Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Manual,<br />

prepared for New York City <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Design and Construction, Accessed 19 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.nyc.gov/html/ddc/downloads/pdf/waste.pdf


Construction and demolition projects worth less than $50,000 are asked to<br />

voluntarily commit to recycle the maximum amount possible from the site. 823<br />

48.2.8 Chicago, USA<br />

A construction and demolition recycling requirement was introduced to the City <strong>of</strong><br />

Chicago in 2004 which required 25% <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition debris produced<br />

on site (as measured by weight) to be recycled. In 2007 the requirement was<br />

increased to 50%. 824 Projects must adhere to 50% recycling if they are:<br />

679<br />

� residential projects <strong>of</strong> four or more units; or<br />

� a construction project which requires a certificate <strong>of</strong> occupancy to issue<br />

from the department <strong>of</strong> buildings; or<br />

� any demolition project costing over $10,000.<br />

Construction debris, as defined in the requirement, includes the following materials:<br />

� bricks, concrete, and other masonry materials;<br />

� rock;<br />

� wood, including non-hazardous painted, treated and coated wood;<br />

� scrap metal;<br />

� plaster;<br />

� gypsum drywall;<br />

� plumbing fixtures and piping;<br />

� non-asbestos insulation;<br />

� ro<strong>of</strong>ing shingles and other ro<strong>of</strong> coverings;<br />

� reclaimed asphalt pavement;<br />

� glass;<br />

� plastics; and<br />

� landscape waste.<br />

48.2.9 Ontario, Canada<br />

Source separation for C&D projects greater than 2,000 square metres is obligatory<br />

under Ontario’s Regulation 103/94, which is an associated regulation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

823 City <strong>of</strong> Portland Office <strong>of</strong> Sustainable Development (2008) Administrative Rules Commercial Solid<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>, Recycling and Compostables, Accessed 15 th January 2008,<br />

http://www.portlandonline.com/osd/index.cfm?a=218220&c=41472<br />

824 City <strong>of</strong> Chicago, Ordinance 11-4-1905 Construction or Demolition Site <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling, Accessed<br />

16 th January 2008,<br />

http://egov.city<strong>of</strong>chicago.org/city/webportal/portalContentItemAction.do?contentOID=536932617&co<br />

ntenTypeName=COC_EDITORIAL&topChannelName=HomePage<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Environmental Protection Action (1990). Mandatory separation is required for brick<br />

and concrete, steel and wood. 825<br />

48.2.10 Alberta, Canada<br />

The Alberta government in Canada are currently out to consultation on a similar<br />

scheme and aim to have mandatory recycling for the construction industry by 2010,<br />

backed with the use <strong>of</strong> a refunded compliance bond system. A preliminary agreement<br />

has been made between the Government <strong>of</strong> Alberta, the Alberta Construction<br />

Association and the Canadian Home Builders’ Association-Alberta. 826<br />

48.2.11 Japan<br />

Under the Construction Material <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Law, which came into effect in<br />

2000, contractors must be responsible for source separation and recycling. Due to<br />

the small size <strong>of</strong> an average property in Japan to which the Recycling Law does apply,<br />

the regulations imply that almost all demolition projects must source separate<br />

wastes. The Law is applied to:<br />

680<br />

1. demolition projects equal to or greater than 80 square metres;<br />

2. construction/extension projects <strong>of</strong> at least 80 square metres;<br />

3. renovation projects <strong>of</strong> at least $870,000; and<br />

4. construction or demolition projects for other than buildings at least<br />

$43,000. 827<br />

In 2001 the Law was updated in order to stipulate a 95% recycling rate for specified<br />

construction materials to be achieved by 2010. Government projects were expected<br />

to be producing zero waste by 2005. 828<br />

48.2.12 Other Countries<br />

It is known that the following countries have minimum recycling standards in place,<br />

but little detail has been identified about each policy.<br />

825 Ontario Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment (2007) A Guide to Source Separation <strong>of</strong> Recycling Materials for<br />

Industrial, Commercial and Industrial Sectors and Multi-Unit Residential Buildings As Required Under<br />

Ontario Regulation 103/94, Accessed 24 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.ene.gov.on.ca/publications/2478e01.pdf<br />

826 Government <strong>of</strong> Alberta (2008) Landmark Agreement Means Less Construction <strong>Waste</strong> in Landfills,<br />

News Release 23 rd October 2008, Accessed 16 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.alberta.ca/acn/200810/246242B8DDAEB-C525-C785-A11A71CAA4E916AE.html<br />

827 R. Tanaka (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction in Japan, Science and Innovation Section, British Embassy<br />

Tokyo, Accessed 30 th October 2008, https://ukinjapanstage.fco.gov.uk/resources/en/pdf/5606907/5633507/071030<strong>Waste</strong>Reduction.pdf<br />

828 Government <strong>of</strong> Japan’s Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment (2001) Construction Material Recycling Law,<br />

Accessed 16 th January 2009, http://www.env.go.jp/en/laws/recycle/09.pdf<br />

29/09/09


Belgium<br />

Following Article 16 in Chapter 4 <strong>of</strong> the Belgian Decree concerning Prevention and<br />

<strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Materials, there must be separate collection <strong>of</strong> C&D waste.<br />

Denmark<br />

The separation <strong>of</strong> C&D waste into clean fractions has been mandatory in Denmark<br />

since 1997. This applies to sites where more than 1 tonne <strong>of</strong> waste is being<br />

produced.<br />

Finland<br />

The separate collection <strong>of</strong> materials from the C&D waste stream is specified in decree<br />

295/1997. C&D waste in Finland must be separated into four categories:<br />

681<br />

1. concrete, brick, ceramic and gypsum;<br />

2. non-impregnated wood wastes;<br />

3. metal wastes; and<br />

4. soil, rocks and dredging wastes. 829<br />

Slovenia<br />

Under its Environmental Protection Act (2001), Slovenia requires separate collection<br />

<strong>of</strong> C&D wastes. 830<br />

48.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

C&D separate collections are predominantly privately co-ordinated and funded, with<br />

the C&D companies taking responsibility for source-separation to attain their recycling<br />

rates.<br />

Where refunded compliance bond schemes are in place, the administration required<br />

is somewhat more complex than were basic requirements to sort are in place. 831 In<br />

order to implement this policy the key organisation will be the permitting authority.<br />

They will be responsible for the following:<br />

� administration <strong>of</strong> certification <strong>of</strong> waste transporters and recycling facilities.<br />

It is fundamental that these services must be accredited in some way in order<br />

829 Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Finland (2000) Environmental Protection Act (86/2000), Accessed<br />

20 th January, http://www.environment.fi/default.asp?node=17869&lan=en#a0.<br />

830 Government <strong>of</strong> the Republic <strong>of</strong> Slovenia (2004) Environment Protection Act (ZVO-1) SOP-2004-01-<br />

1694, Accessed 20 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.mop.gov.si/fileadmin/mop.gov.si/pageuploads/zakonodaja/okolje/en/zvo_s.pdf<br />

831 Actually, checking that all companies do what they say they will is not straightforward. Indeed, the<br />

refunded compliance bond approach effectively makes it possible to track C&D waste more effectively,<br />

whilst also allowing for a more direct check over companies’ activities.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


682<br />

29/09/09<br />

to ensure that the mechanism for checking waste works efficiently, i.e. that<br />

paperwork received can be used as pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> recycling;<br />

� sending out permit application forms and the administration involved with<br />

receipt <strong>of</strong> completed permit application forms;<br />

� receiving the administration fee;<br />

� receiving, and holding, the deposit;<br />

� send out permits to allow work to commence; and<br />

� implementation <strong>of</strong> a checking mechanism to decide if the deposit can be<br />

returned, or not.<br />

48.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

� Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry, Environment and Water<br />

<strong>Management</strong>, 2006, Federal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan 2006: Suitable for<br />

Nature and Mankind. Available at:<br />

http://www.bundesabfallwirtschaftsplan.at/Austria<br />

� R. Tanaka (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction in Japan, Science and Innovation<br />

Section, British Embassy Tokyo, Accessed 30 th October 2008,<br />

https://ukinjapanstage.fco.gov.uk/resources/en/pdf/5606907/5633507/071030<strong>Waste</strong>Reduc<br />

tion.pdf<br />

� Gruzen Samton LLP with City Green Inc. (2003) Construction and<br />

Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Manual, prepared for New York City <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Design<br />

and Construction, Accessed 19 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.nyc.gov/html/ddc/downloads/pdf/waste.pdf<br />

There is an overall lack <strong>of</strong> evaluation studies with regards to this policy in the<br />

construction and demolition context. The majority <strong>of</strong> resources were located on<br />

individual city, county or country websites which lay down the specifications <strong>of</strong> the<br />

policy but do not generally make comparisons to other similar policies, or evaluate<br />

their own.<br />

48.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The main environmental benefits from the mandatory requirement for separate<br />

collection and subsequent recovery <strong>of</strong> C&D waste materials are:<br />

� the recovery <strong>of</strong> homogenous building materials for use as secondary raw<br />

materials and/or fill materials, typically at lower cost than if primary material<br />

was used;<br />

� the diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill (thereby reducing the utilisation <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill volumes and saving companies costs associated with sending waste to<br />

landfill);<br />

� the saving <strong>of</strong> primary materials, thereby protecting the landscape by removing<br />

less material and improving groundwater protection; and<br />

� the savings, in terms <strong>of</strong> embodied energy, from materials recycling.


The UK Environment Agency have built a carbon calculator for buildings which helps<br />

to estimate the potential for carbon savings through increased use <strong>of</strong> recycled<br />

materials in buildings. Carbon emissions for several different building materials are<br />

shown in Table 48-3.<br />

Table 48-3: Environmental Impact <strong>of</strong> Selected C&D Materials<br />

Aggregate<br />

Aluminium<br />

Copper<br />

Steel<br />

683<br />

Material<br />

Material<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Carbon Carbon footprint footprint<br />

footprint<br />

(tCO (tCO2/t) (tCO (tCO /t) /t)<br />

0% recycled 0.008<br />

100% recycled 0.004<br />

Virgin 12.65<br />

Predominantly recycled 1.02<br />

Virgin 5.57<br />

100% recycled (high grade/low grade) 3.98 / 1.39<br />

Virgin 2.90<br />

Predominantly recycled 0.97<br />

Source: Environment Agency, Carbon Calculator for Construction Industries, Accessed 17 th February<br />

2009, http://www.environment-agency.gov.uk/static/documents/carbon_calculator_2_1883909.xls<br />

It can be seen that using 100% recycled material always reduces the carbon<br />

emissions but the benefit varies greatly between material. There is great potential for<br />

decreasing the environmental impact <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition projects through<br />

focusing on materials other than aggregates. Although aggregates are the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

the C&D waste stream by weight, it is apparent that there are disproportionate<br />

environmental benefits to be gained through focusing policy on the other materials. In<br />

particular, the benefits from recycling the material arise through the differentials<br />

between the figures in the above Table for the primary and secondary material.<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> aluminium, high grade copper, low grade copper and steel, therefore,<br />

generate benefits <strong>of</strong> the order 11.63 tonnes CO2, 1.59 tonnes CO2, 4.18 tonnes CO2<br />

and 1.93 tonnes CO2 respectively.<br />

Quantifying the environmental benefit as a result <strong>of</strong> mandatory recycling is at this<br />

stage hard. For example, the Netherlands has a high C&D recycling rate (90%+) but it<br />

was relatively high (74%) before the implementation <strong>of</strong> any focused C&D waste policy<br />

instruments in 1990. Following this they implemented 4 policies:<br />

1) separation <strong>of</strong> recyclable materials from demolition projects was announced in<br />

1993;<br />

2) landfill tax in 1996;<br />

3) the building material decree in 1999 (see Section 47.0); and


4) landfill ban for specific recyclable and combustible materials, which impacted<br />

upon C&D waste, in 2000. 832<br />

The evolution in recycling rates is shown in Figure 48-1, where the rate <strong>of</strong> recycling is<br />

seen to increase to over 90% during 1995, when the impending implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

the landfill tax was announced, and before the other policies had been formally<br />

implemented. 833 This suggests that the requirement to sort may have had a<br />

significant impact, which was supported by the announcement <strong>of</strong> the landfill tax.<br />

Figure 48-1: Proportion <strong>Waste</strong> to Landfill and C&D Recycling Rates in the Netherlands<br />

(%)<br />

684<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005<br />

Year<br />

Recycling Rate<br />

Proportion <strong>Waste</strong> to Landfill<br />

Source data: OECD (2002) Case Studies on <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments for Environmentally Sustainable<br />

Buildings, Accessed 21 st January 2009,<br />

http://www.olis.oecd.org/olis/2001doc.nsf/LinkTo/NT00000C46/$FILE/JT00128202.PDF<br />

The Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry report that the annual generation <strong>of</strong><br />

C&D waste and excavated soil in Austria is estimated to be approximately 28 million<br />

tonnes, therefore accounting for approximately 52 % <strong>of</strong> the total waste generated in<br />

Austria each year. Since the Ordinance on the Separation <strong>of</strong> Materials Accumulated<br />

832 Although the ban covers construction and demolition waste, in practice, the way the ban is<br />

implemented tends to imply that such wastes are still likely to be accepted at Dutch landfills since the<br />

ban is implemented through reference to a density threshold.<br />

833 OECD (2002) Case Studies on <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments for Environmentally Sustainable Buildings,<br />

Accessed 21 st January 2009,<br />

http://www.olis.oecd.org/olis/2001doc.nsf/LinkTo/NT00000C46/$FILE/JT00128202.PDF


during Construction Work came into force, recycling <strong>of</strong> C&D waste has increased from<br />

15 % in 1985 to more than 70 % in 2006. However, it is unknown how much <strong>of</strong> this<br />

increase can be apportioned to this policy mechanism. 834<br />

Positive feedback from the scheme in San Jose shows that 98% <strong>of</strong> contractors<br />

produce the relevant documents in order to allow them to receive their deposit back.<br />

Depending on whether the project is public or private, this means that recycling rates<br />

<strong>of</strong> 75% and 50% respectively are being achieved. 835 That having been said, these<br />

targets are not so challenging, so that these may have already been being met in the<br />

pre-existing situation. Even so, a useful attribute <strong>of</strong> the refunded compliance bond<br />

policy is that it is flexible with respect to the target setting which should be achieved.<br />

48.6 Implementation Costs<br />

Costs will mainly be incurred by the contractor who will have to ensure that they are<br />

adhering to the policy either through setting up source separation containers on site,<br />

arranging collection by registered transporters or ensuring material is delivered to<br />

certified sorting and reprocessing facilities.<br />

The enforcing authority will also have costs for administration <strong>of</strong> the permit system,<br />

production <strong>of</strong> awareness campaigns and resources, and enforcement <strong>of</strong>ficers, but no<br />

information could be found to quantify this cost.<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> refunded compliance bonds, the administrative fee is expected to cover<br />

all such costs. As stated above, in California, this is estimated as 0.3% <strong>of</strong> project<br />

costs.<br />

48.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

As contractors have to undertake source separation <strong>of</strong> recyclables on site they may<br />

also begin to consider the following:<br />

685<br />

� on-site separation practices;<br />

� demolition methods which allow for the materials to be source separated more<br />

easily (see Annex 45.0);<br />

� re-using the material from demolition projects in construction projects;<br />

� using products with recycled content in the construction phases, for example<br />

recycled aggregate; and<br />

� constructing buildings in such a way that allows for straightforward<br />

disassembly, material sorting and recycling, at the end <strong>of</strong> their life, e.g.<br />

834 Federal Ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture and Forestry, Environment and Water <strong>Management</strong> (2006) Federal<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan 2006: Suitable for Nature and Mankind. Available at:<br />

http://www.bundesabfallwirtschaftsplan.at/<br />

835 Gruzen Samton LLP with City Green Inc. (2003) Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Manual,<br />

prepared for New York City <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Design and Construction, Accessed 19 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.nyc.gov/html/ddc/downloads/pdf/waste.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


686<br />

29/09/09<br />

Singapore’s use <strong>of</strong> prefabricated concrete slabs. 836 There are many examples<br />

<strong>of</strong> voluntary codes <strong>of</strong> practice which encourage sustainable construction and<br />

demolition which have not been included in this review as they are not<br />

considered a policy. For example, the Code <strong>of</strong> Practice on Buildable Design in<br />

Singapore and the Code for Sustainable Homes in Scotland, England and<br />

Wales. However, it is possible that in the future these may be mandated, as<br />

has been the trend for other initiatives or schemes which are now considered<br />

to be policies.<br />

48.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

Social and distributional consequences would only be expected where:<br />

� either, the policy differentiated between companies; or<br />

� the costs introduced by the policy had a significant impact on the price <strong>of</strong><br />

construction projects targeted by the policy.<br />

In reality, the policies seem either to impose minimal costs (companies may even<br />

reduce waste management costs, depending upon the other policies in place).<br />

In cases where refunded compliance bonds are in place, the bond is typically related<br />

to the size <strong>of</strong> the project. The bond itself can be refunded on achievement <strong>of</strong> the<br />

required target. In principle, those with more pressing cash-flow problems would find<br />

it more difficult to put up the compliance bond in advance.<br />

Clearly, a beneficiary should be the reprocessing sector, in particular, accredited<br />

facilities.<br />

48.9 Complementary Policies<br />

Unlike the minimum recycling standards for household and C&I waste materials, the<br />

recycling standards <strong>of</strong> waste streams in C&D are not underpinned by financial<br />

support policies such as producer responsibility and pay-by-use. However, examples<br />

<strong>of</strong> refunded compliance bonds have been seen in the USA which provide a financial<br />

incentive to reach the set recycling targets. Also, in Austria there is a reduction in<br />

waste management fees for separately collected demolition waste. 837<br />

An alternative policy to mandatory recycling is to mandate the use <strong>of</strong> recycled<br />

products, thereby forcing recycling rates up to ensure the recycled material is<br />

available. Due to the close association between the two policy mechanisms it is<br />

possible that both could be simultaneously implemented in one policy. It has been<br />

common in the past for such guidelines to be included in green public procurement<br />

836 AEA Technology (2007) <strong>International</strong> Approaches to <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Minimisation, Final<br />

Report for Defra (BREW), Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.crwplatform.co.uk/conwaste/assets/Publications/2006-7-Reports/<strong>International</strong>-<br />

Approaches-to-<strong>Waste</strong>-Prevention-and-Minimisation.pdf<br />

837 European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> [Online],<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Instruments [Accessed 8th September 2008].


codes. For example, Korea introduced ‘The Act on the Promotion <strong>of</strong> Construction<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Recycling’ in 2005 which mandated use <strong>of</strong> recycled aggregate for construction<br />

work contracted by a public agency. 838 Similarly, in Australia, state projects <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

mandate the use <strong>of</strong> recycled materials for pavements, earthworks and drainage. 839<br />

C&D recycling is also strongly incentivised by policy measures which discourage<br />

disposal such as landfill tax, landfill bans and, specific to C&D, aggregates tax (see<br />

Section 46.0). Without these policies providing such strong economic drivers for<br />

construction and demolition companies to recycle it is unlikely that such high<br />

recycling rates would be achieved within the sector. It is notable that in the US, where<br />

disposal costs have tended to remain low, the targets being set are less ambitious<br />

than those in Europe and Asia, possibly reflecting a concern that the measures might<br />

imply additional costs to developers, rather than implying savings, as might be more<br />

common in EU countries (where higher disposal costs apply).<br />

The continuing problem in analysing the policies is how to attribute cause and effect<br />

directly to one policy when they are working in parallel towards the same goal. The US<br />

cases are <strong>of</strong> particular interest in this respect since there are fewer complementary<br />

policies.<br />

48.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The cost <strong>of</strong> demolition is likely to increase due to greater care that has to be taken<br />

when source separating the demolished materials. However, savings are likely to be<br />

made due to decreased disposal costs, especially in those countries where a landfill<br />

tax is in place. In the case <strong>of</strong> Austria, one study compares the cost <strong>of</strong> treatment and<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> mixed/non separated waste with separated waste. The results show an<br />

overall reduction <strong>of</strong> €11.5/m 3 in the cost <strong>of</strong> treatment and disposal <strong>of</strong> separated<br />

waste, compared to mixed waste. 840<br />

48.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

For the deposit schemes in California fines can range from $100/day to $1,500/day<br />

relative to the size <strong>of</strong> the development. Enforcement in these cases is undertaken by<br />

the relevant city authority and no evidence was identified which indicated how<br />

effective the enforcement <strong>of</strong> the system is.<br />

838 Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment Republic <strong>of</strong> Korea (2007) Act on the Promotion <strong>of</strong> Construction <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Recycling, Accessed 16 th January 2009,<br />

http://eng.me.go.kr/docs/laws/laws.html?topmenu=D&cat=400<br />

839 AEA Technology (2007) <strong>International</strong> Approaches to <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and Minimisation, Final<br />

Report for Defra (BREW), Accessed 15 th October 2008,<br />

http://www.crwplatform.co.uk/conwaste/assets/Publications/2006-7-Reports/<strong>International</strong>-<br />

Approaches-to-<strong>Waste</strong>-Prevention-and-Minimisation.pdf<br />

840 C. Pladerer (2006) ‘Towards Sustainable Plastic Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

in Europe’ Initiatives for a Sustainable Plastic C&D <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in Europe; The Case <strong>of</strong> Austria,<br />

Presentation by the Okologie Institut for the European Workshop, Brussels, 24 th April 2006.<br />

687<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


In San Diego, where the mandatory recycling system is incentivised by a deposit<br />

refund system, refunds for projects recycling less than the required amount will be<br />

pro-rated according to the recycling rate achieved by the project. This system is<br />

administered by the City <strong>of</strong> San Diego’s Environmental Services <strong>Department</strong>.<br />

The City <strong>of</strong> Portland has the authority to inspect a site, whether or not a complaint has<br />

been made. Following the inspection a letter <strong>of</strong> non-compliance will be issued if this<br />

was the case. The letter gives the contractor 30 days in which to resolve the problem.<br />

Further non-compliance leads to court action. 841<br />

In Ontario, lack <strong>of</strong> enforcement issues have been raised due to the self-regulatory<br />

approach that has been taken. Although the Ontario Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment<br />

Enforcement Branch <strong>of</strong> Operations Division and Regional and District Offices do visit<br />

sites, check plans, and monitor recycling activities being undertaken, it is more <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

self-regulated. 842<br />

In Chicago enforcement is undertaken by the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment but<br />

permits must be applied for, and documentation must be submitted to the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Buildings, in order to prove compliance with the recycling standards.<br />

Provision <strong>of</strong> misleading information in documentation regarding levels <strong>of</strong> recycling<br />

that have been achieved can result in personal fines <strong>of</strong> $200 to $500 and potential<br />

revocation <strong>of</strong> the contractor’s license. Contractors are subject to fines as shown in<br />

Table 48-4. 843<br />

Table 48-4: Fines Implemented Under the City <strong>of</strong> Chicago's Recycling Ordinance<br />

688<br />

Size Size Size <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Construction Construction or or Demolition Demolition Project Project<br />

Fine Fine<br />

Fine<br />

10,000 square feet or more<br />

10,000 square feet or less<br />

29/09/09<br />

$1,000 for each percentage point <strong>of</strong> difference<br />

between the amount required to be<br />

recycled/reused and the amount actually<br />

recycled/reused.<br />

$500 for each percentage point <strong>of</strong> difference<br />

between the amount required to be<br />

recycled/reused and the amount actually<br />

recycled/reused.<br />

841 City <strong>of</strong> Portland Office <strong>of</strong> Sustainable Development (2008) Administrative Rules Commercial Solid<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>, Recycling and Compostables, Accessed 15 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.portlandonline.com/osd/index.cfm?a=218220&c=41472<br />

842 The Recycling Council <strong>of</strong> Ontario (RCO) (2006) Let’s Climb Another Molehill: An Examination <strong>of</strong><br />

Construction, Demolition and Renovation (CRD) <strong>Waste</strong> Diversion in Canada and Associated<br />

Greenhouse Gas Emission Impacts, Accessed 24 th October 2008<br />

http://www.recycle.nrcan.gc.ca/documents/Full%20Molehill%20report%20-%20ENG.pdf<br />

843 City <strong>of</strong> Chicago, Ordinance 11-4-1905 Construction or Demolition Site <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling, Accessed<br />

16 th January 2008,<br />

http://egov.city<strong>of</strong>chicago.org/city/webportal/portalContentItemAction.do?contentOID=536932617&co<br />

ntenTypeName=COC_EDITORIAL&topChannelName=HomePage


In Japan, the lead contractor is responsible for source separation and recycling, even<br />

if this will be carried out by one or many subcontractors. This resulted in any<br />

additional cost being carried by the lead contractor and subsequently resulted in flytipping<br />

when they could not recover the full cost.<br />

48.12 Lessons Learned<br />

The potential for mandating recycling rates can be highlighted by a Japanese<br />

construction company, Sekisui House, which voluntarily achieved zero waste at their<br />

construction sites in 2005. Materials were source separated in 27 categories on site<br />

which were further sorted into 60 categories at a MRF. They report that the average<br />

waste from site was reduced from 2.9 tonnes to 1.8 tonnes, which went on to be<br />

reused or recycled. In one month they reported savings <strong>of</strong> U.S.$350,000. 844 Since<br />

2005, all Government construction and demolition projects must be zero waste but<br />

no evaluation reports regarding this requirement could be found.<br />

48.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

Firstly, as already mentioned in Section 48.9, policies which make disposal more<br />

expensive are thought to be the underlying driver for this policy by enabling<br />

contractors to make a financial saving through increasing recycling rates from their<br />

construction and demolition projects.<br />

Also, industry support is important since the cost <strong>of</strong> complying with the policy falls<br />

with them. Success from the implementation <strong>of</strong> the scheme in San Jose has shown<br />

that processors have been positive about becoming certified in order to ensure they<br />

retain their customer base. The City <strong>of</strong> San Jose reports that obtaining documentation<br />

from the processors in order to prove mandatory recycling rates are being achieved<br />

was straightforward. 845<br />

Furthermore, a permitting authority needs to be assigned in order to monitor and<br />

enforce the policy. Further details regarding the expected role <strong>of</strong> the permitting<br />

authority are outlined in Section 48.3.<br />

Finally, there is likely to be merit in setting a clear target for recycling <strong>of</strong> construction<br />

and demolition waste, this being necessary for projects where the refunded<br />

compliance bond is the policy <strong>of</strong> choice.<br />

844 Resource Recovery Forum (2006) Japan – Sekisui House Achieves Zero <strong>Waste</strong> at New Construction<br />

Site, Accessed 16 th January 2008,<br />

http://www.resourcesnotwaste.org/members/private/news/view.php?newsItem_ID=1662<br />

845 Gruzen Samton LLP with City Green Inc. (2003) Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Manual,<br />

prepared for New York City <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Design and Construction, Accessed 19 th January 2009,<br />

http://www.nyc.gov/html/ddc/downloads/pdf/waste.pdf<br />

689<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


49.0 Incentives Affecting Construction and<br />

Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> - Belgium<br />

The past 10 years, policy regarding construction and demolition waste (C&D waste)<br />

was mainly focused on attaining high recycling rates. In 1995, a target was set for the<br />

recycling rate that should be achieved by 2000, i.e. 75% <strong>of</strong> C&D waste. This goal was<br />

achieved rather easily, with a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> more than 85% in 2000.<br />

By comparison, no clear goal was set for the reduction <strong>of</strong> C&D waste; a reduction was<br />

sought by awareness rising campaigns like guides on good practice, and the PRESTI<br />

programme (Prevention Stimulating Programme) that financed studies and pilotprojects<br />

on waste prevention. Initiatives and programmes such as these are<br />

discussed in Annex 60.0.<br />

In 2007, a new Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong> Master plan 2007-2010 was<br />

implemented. Emphasis again was put on recycling and especially re-use <strong>of</strong> C&D<br />

waste, with e.g. high environmental standards and certification <strong>of</strong> aggregates, and<br />

specifications for selective dismantling. With regard to the prevention <strong>of</strong> C&D waste, a<br />

study is currently being performed analysing the feasibility <strong>of</strong> establishing<br />

environmental performance requirements with respect to material use in<br />

construction.<br />

690<br />

29/09/09


50.0 Minimum Recycling Standards (Construction<br />

and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>) - Germany<br />

The Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance 846 regulates the recovery and disposal <strong>of</strong><br />

commercial municipal waste, and construction and demolition waste. The principal<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> the Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance (GewAbfV) is the segregation <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

fractions (four fractions for building and demolition waste: metallic waste, glass,<br />

plastics and concrete) in order achieve greater feedstock or energy recovery (i.e. the<br />

aim is to remove wastes which are not readily combustible to allow for use <strong>of</strong> the<br />

residual in energy recovery facilities).<br />

Particular attention should be paid to two aspects:<br />

691<br />

1. the approach employed by the ordinance with regard to recovery quotas; and<br />

2. the special regulations for building and demolition waste.<br />

The recovery quotas apply to the recovery <strong>of</strong> waste in pre-treatment plants. However,<br />

not all accumulated (and recoverable) waste arrives at such plants; consequently, the<br />

question arises whether the recovery quota as an instrument actually achieves its<br />

intended effect.<br />

The period between the accumulation <strong>of</strong> the waste (demolition <strong>of</strong> a house) until<br />

transport to a pre-treatment plant, that is, the period in which the selection,<br />

segregation and collection <strong>of</strong> recyclable waste takes place, is generally defined by the<br />

KWTB voluntary commitment declaration. In this regard the question also arises<br />

whether the Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance only achieves the effect intended by the<br />

legislator by means <strong>of</strong> an additional timely voluntary commitment declaration.<br />

Prior to this, the building industry was fulfilling the recycling quotas imposed by the<br />

voluntary commitment declaration. Accordingly, the instrument is functioning, and<br />

legislative regulations (to be integrated in the Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance) are<br />

currently not absolutely necessary.<br />

On the other hand, the specifications already given for building and demolition waste<br />

in the Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance must be studied in more detail. For example, the<br />

list <strong>of</strong> building materials (e.g. plastics, glass, concrete) does not include such things<br />

as insulating materials or high-quality building materials (concrete from structural<br />

engineering). However, there are reservations regarding insulating materials due to<br />

heavy soiling because recovery <strong>of</strong> soiled (usually mixed with other building materials)<br />

insulating materials is only possible with restrictions. In practice, the problem <strong>of</strong><br />

mixing occurs for insulating materials in particular. Insulating materials are therefore<br />

explicitly mentioned as mixed waste in the LAGA implementation notes.<br />

846 (2002) Ordinance on the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>s <strong>of</strong> Commercial Origin and Certain<br />

Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>s <strong>of</strong> 19.06.2002, Federal Law Gazette, pp.1938.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Due to the failure to list these materials in the Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance,<br />

however, the limited existing potential for the recovery <strong>of</strong> insulating materials during<br />

demolition is not being exhausted. Wood, in turn, does not come under the regime <strong>of</strong><br />

the Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance, but is covered by the <strong>Waste</strong> Wood Ordinance<br />

(AltholzV); this divides wood waste from the building sector into several waste wood<br />

categories (see Annex III <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Wood Ordinance). 847 The requirements placed<br />

on treatment prior to reuse then depend on the category.<br />

The LAGA implementation notes put into concrete terms the principal regulations<br />

contained in the Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance. 848 In parts they contain information<br />

which could not be included in the Ordinance for fear <strong>of</strong> bloating the text or because it<br />

represents background information only.<br />

The structure employed by the ordinance follows two routes:<br />

692<br />

1. the system <strong>of</strong> principles applying to commercial municipal waste is also<br />

adopted for the explicitly emphasised building and demolition waste listed<br />

using a separate system; and<br />

2. the building and demolition waste, in turn, is differentiated into discrete and<br />

mixed waste fractions<br />

� new-build (in particular structural engineering);<br />

� refurbishment, modernisation and renovation; and<br />

� demolition, where individual components or building materials are<br />

removed separately (selective demolition).<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> demolition, the LAGA points out that selective demolition may be<br />

obligatory depending on the Federal state involved. However, regulations involving<br />

Federal state laws have not yet been identified.<br />

Beside this, the implementation notes also address mixed waste and briefly describe<br />

the situation surrounding the origin and types <strong>of</strong> accumulating waste mixtures in<br />

order to clarify fields <strong>of</strong> action for the executive agency. This shows that mixed<br />

building and demolition waste primarily occurs where no selective demolition is<br />

practiced. In most cases, these types <strong>of</strong> waste consist <strong>of</strong> mineral building waste<br />

fractions and, in addition, bitumen mixtures, insulating materials or gypsum-based<br />

building materials.<br />

It is felt that the current framework in place for dealing with C&D waste is insufficient.<br />

Not least because <strong>of</strong> numerous problematic substances (e.g. asbestos, heavy metals)<br />

and incompatible substances (e.g. gypsum in concrete recycling, insulation materials<br />

manufactured from fibres, etc.) contained in the building material stock, which in<br />

practice make successful high-quality recycling more difficult or even hinder it<br />

completely, it is felt that a means <strong>of</strong> optimal material segregation by selective<br />

demolition should be sought.<br />

847 Ordinance <strong>of</strong> 15.08.02, Federal Law Gazette, pp.3302.<br />

848 Implementation notes <strong>of</strong> the Working Group <strong>of</strong> the Federal States on <strong>Waste</strong> (LAGA) to the<br />

Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> Ordinance, passed on 26.03.03.<br />

29/09/09


POLICIES FOR RESIDUAL WASTE<br />

693<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


51.0 The Landfill Directive – Current Situation<br />

Meeting the targets under Article 5 <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive is a major challenge for<br />

Ireland. Some detailed consideration is given to how Ireland might meet these targets<br />

in this Section, taking into account the current situation and the potential for change<br />

in the time available.<br />

First, we review data for municipal waste. We then consider progress towards the<br />

Directive targets, and plans in place to meet these. We discuss the potential for<br />

meeting these targets, first in an ‘unconstrained’ manner, and then, taking into<br />

account the institutional constraints currently in place.<br />

By way <strong>of</strong> reminder, Article 5 (2) <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive states, regarding national<br />

strategies for reducing the landfilling <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste: 849<br />

694<br />

29/09/09<br />

2. This strategy shall ensure that:<br />

(a) not later than five years after the date laid down in Article 18(1),<br />

biodegradable municipal waste going to landfills must be reduced to<br />

75 % <strong>of</strong> the total amount (by weight) <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste<br />

produced in 1995 or the latest year before 1995 for which<br />

standardised Eurostat data is available<br />

(b) not later than eight years after the date laid down in Article 18(1),<br />

biodegradable municipal waste going to landfills must be reduced to<br />

50 % <strong>of</strong> the total amount (by weight) <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste<br />

produced in 1995 or the latest year before 1995 for which<br />

standardised Eurostat data is available;<br />

(c) not later than 15 years after the date laid down in Article 18(1),<br />

biodegradable municipal waste going to landfills must be reduced to<br />

35 % <strong>of</strong> the total amount (by weight) <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste<br />

produced in 1995 or the latest year before 1995 for which<br />

standardised Eurostat data is available.<br />

Two years before the date referred to in paragraph (c) the Council shall reexamine<br />

the above target, on the basis <strong>of</strong> a report from the Commission on<br />

the practical experience gained by Member States in the pursuance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

targets laid down in paragraphs (a) and (b) accompanied, if appropriate, by a<br />

proposal with a view to confirming or amending this target in order to ensure a<br />

high level <strong>of</strong> environmental protection.<br />

Member States which in 1995 or the latest year before 1995 for which<br />

standardised EUROSTAT data is available put more than 80 % <strong>of</strong> their<br />

collected municipal waste to landfill may postpone the attainment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

targets set out in paragraphs (a), (b), or (c) by a period not exceeding four<br />

years. Member States intending to make use <strong>of</strong> this provision shall inform in<br />

849 Council Directive 1999/31/EC <strong>of</strong> 26 April 1999 on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste Official Journal L 182 ,<br />

16/07/1999 pp. 1 – 19.


695<br />

advance the Commission <strong>of</strong> their decision. The Commission shall inform other<br />

Member States and the European Parliament <strong>of</strong> these decisions.<br />

51.1 Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> – Quantities and Growth Rates<br />

In Ireland, municipal waste is defined as follows:<br />

household waste as well as commercial, industrial and street cleansing waste<br />

which because <strong>of</strong> its nature and composition is similar to household waste.<br />

In statistical reporting by the EPA, there appears to be:<br />

1) no commercial waste which is not deemed part <strong>of</strong> municipal waste;<br />

2) no street cleansing waste which is not deemed part <strong>of</strong> municipal waste; and<br />

3) no industrial waste which is deemed part <strong>of</strong> municipal waste.<br />

Indeed, municipal waste appears to be defined as:<br />

Household waste plus street sweepings plus commercial waste,<br />

where the following definitions apply<br />

1) Household Household waste waste is waste produced within the curtilage <strong>of</strong> a building or selfcontained<br />

part <strong>of</strong> a building used for the purposes <strong>of</strong> living accommodation.<br />

2) Commercial Commercial waste waste is the waste that is produced from a number <strong>of</strong> diverse<br />

sources, including shops, <strong>of</strong>fices and commercial premises, such as paper and<br />

cardboard, plastics, organics and glass etc.<br />

Figure 51-1shows the evolution <strong>of</strong> the total quantity <strong>of</strong> municipal waste and its subcomponents<br />

have changed over the last twelve years. It is clear that the quantities<br />

have generally increased.<br />

The total quantity <strong>of</strong> municipal waste has increased at a compound rate <strong>of</strong> 5.6% per<br />

annum. This growth rate masks the differences seen in the sub-streams.<br />

As can be seen from Figure 51-1, the contribution to total MSW from street sweepings<br />

is very small. The more important streams are commercial waste and household<br />

waste.<br />

51.1.1 Household <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Growth rates for household waste is as follows:<br />

� Household waste 3.8% per annum over the last 12 years;<br />

� Household waste 2% per annum over the last 6 years<br />

� Per capita household waste flat over the last 6 years<br />

Ireland has experienced significant changes in population in recent years. This is<br />

shown in Figure 51-2. The country is effectively returning to population levels <strong>of</strong> the<br />

1860s, from a low point achieved in the 1960s. Net migration, which has been<br />

negative in every intercensal period bar one since before the 1920s, turned strongly<br />

positive from the 1990s onward.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 51-1: Evolution <strong>of</strong> MSW and its Components, 1995-2007<br />

Tonnes <strong>Waste</strong><br />

696<br />

4,000,000<br />

3,500,000<br />

3,000,000<br />

2,500,000<br />

2,000,000<br />

1,500,000<br />

1,000,000<br />

500,000<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007<br />

Year<br />

Household <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Commercial <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Street Sweepings<br />

MSW<br />

Source: EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2001, EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007<br />

Figure 51-2: Changes in Population in Ireland<br />

Source: CSO (2008) Statistical Yearbook <strong>of</strong> Ireland 2008.<br />

The strong growth in municipal waste is, <strong>of</strong> course, driven in part by household waste,<br />

but this does not seem to be the strongest driver. Per capita household waste arisings


have stabilised over the last six years. It would appear, therefore, that the rate <strong>of</strong><br />

population growth is an important driver <strong>of</strong> household waste growth.<br />

Curtis et al have sought to estimate determinants <strong>of</strong> household waste growth in<br />

Ireland. 850 This work is <strong>of</strong> interest since it is one <strong>of</strong> few attempts to elicit such<br />

parameters in Ireland. The authors derive an income elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand for waste<br />

services <strong>of</strong> 1.08. They themselves note that figures in excess <strong>of</strong> 1 are highly unusual<br />

in the literature. This is the figure used in the ISus model to predict future waste<br />

growth. This, coupled with estimates <strong>of</strong> growth for the economy going forward,<br />

suggests considerable – one might say, worryingly high - growth in household waste,<br />

increasing to around 3.2 million tonnes in 2025.<br />

It seems likely that countries experiencing rapid growth from relatively low levels<br />

(compared with the most wealthy nations), as Ireland has done, would tend to exhibit<br />

high income elasticities <strong>of</strong> demand for waste services. However, these might well<br />

show some decline as consumption patterns adjust to higher levels <strong>of</strong> real per capita<br />

disposable income. Generally, constant elasticity models become less reliable over<br />

non marginal changes in prices or incomes. We doubt that this parameter would<br />

remain at this level in the future (and one might doubt the data where it suggests it<br />

has been this high, even in the past).<br />

51.1.2 Commercial <strong>Waste</strong><br />

697<br />

� Commercial waste 9% per annum over the 12 year period<br />

� Commercial waste 8% per annum over the last 6 years<br />

Commercial waste growth has been a staggering 9% per annum over the same 12<br />

year period. It is difficult to explain this rapid growth solely through appeal to<br />

economic growth, especially given the flat ‘per household waste’ quantity over recent<br />

years.<br />

This could reflect problems, referred to in EPA Reports and in discussion with EPA<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficials, <strong>of</strong> classification <strong>of</strong> waste types. However, it seems irregular misclassification<br />

could lead to such a (consistently) large growth rate, not least since some<br />

classification problems might be expected to move waste in and out <strong>of</strong> one<br />

classification from one year to the next.<br />

The stark fact remains that according to the available data, commercial waste has<br />

more than tripled over a twelve year period. There must be questions to be asked<br />

regarding the accuracy <strong>of</strong> the growth rates reported above. To what extent are these<br />

genuine, or do they suggest inconsistencies, across time periods, in reporting? Is<br />

commercial waste increasingly being mixed with other materials? Is this leading to<br />

over-reporting <strong>of</strong> commercial waste?<br />

In 1995, commercial waste was only around 35% <strong>of</strong> household waste. Now, the<br />

quantities are converging. The growth in commercial waste is well above reported<br />

850 John Curtis, Seán Lyons and Abigail O’Callaghan-Platt (2009) Managing Household <strong>Waste</strong> in<br />

Ireland: Behavioural Parameters and <strong>Policy</strong> Options, ESRI Working Paper 295, July 2009.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


GDP growth (in real terms) whilst per capita household waste has remained constant<br />

in recent times, even during a period (to 2007) in which per capita GDP continued to<br />

rise. 851 There is at least a hint that the growth rate which is derived from past<br />

statistics is misleadingly high.<br />

51.1.3 Implications <strong>of</strong> Different Growth Rates<br />

The different growth rates for the two streams have led to a situation in which<br />

commercial waste, having accounted for only 26% <strong>of</strong> municipal waste in 1995, now<br />

accounts for 46% <strong>of</strong> municipal waste.<br />

This is significant for a number <strong>of</strong> reasons:<br />

698<br />

� First, under market oriented conditions, where dry recycling is concerned,<br />

commercial waste tends to be recycled to a greater extent than household<br />

waste. The increased proportion <strong>of</strong> commercial waste in municipal waste will<br />

have had the effect <strong>of</strong> helping to increase recycling rates for municipal waste<br />

(and so, over the last decade, it has proven in Ireland);<br />

� Second, in respect <strong>of</strong> institutional issues considered in this review, a move to<br />

give unequivocal control over delivering collection services to the local<br />

authorities is likely to affect household waste only. This would mean that as far<br />

as municipal waste is concerned, the proportion <strong>of</strong> the waste which would be<br />

subject to clear local authority control is only approximately half the total<br />

municipal waste, as currently defined;<br />

� Third, and as a related point, a substantial proportion <strong>of</strong> biodegradable<br />

municipal waste (BMW) – the subject <strong>of</strong> Landfill Directive targets – has no<br />

obvious single type <strong>of</strong> ‘addressee’ in terms <strong>of</strong> ensuring targets cascading down<br />

from the national level. Probably the only addressee could be the collector, but<br />

if such a policy proved difficult to enforce, then the approach to meeting<br />

landfill directive targets would need to be based on a different, probably<br />

regulatory approach; and<br />

� Fourth, as a consequence <strong>of</strong> this, even if institutional changes were made to<br />

ensure local authorities could be made fully responsible for the management<br />

<strong>of</strong> household waste, with targets applied to them, a different approach would<br />

be required for the commercial waste.<br />

This has implications for the design <strong>of</strong> policy. Since the commercial waste stream is,<br />

and is proposed to continue being, more responsive to market-oriented policies,<br />

policy has to give certainty to the market regarding the requirement to deal with<br />

biodegradable municipal waste in ways other than landfilling, either through market<br />

851 It can perhaps be appreciated, from this discussion, why the projections made in the ISus model<br />

with regard to waste quantities are unlikely to be accurate. The ISus model assumes that the<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> waste per household, with respect to real disposable income, is perfectly elastic. It<br />

assumes also that the waste generation by commerce and industry is perfectly elastic with respect to<br />

real output and turnover (presumably in real terms), respectively. It would be a mistake to make<br />

forward plansd on the basis <strong>of</strong> these projections.<br />

29/09/09


ased instruments, or through regulatory mechanisms, or through a combination <strong>of</strong><br />

both.<br />

51.2 Recycling <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

The recycling rate for household waste was 7% in 2001. It has increased to 26% in<br />

2007. These rates can be compared with commercial waste recycling rates <strong>of</strong> 24%<br />

and 48% in 2001 and 2007, respectively.<br />

It is important to understand the differences between the two and the potential for<br />

performance to improve in both streams.<br />

The most recent EPA <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007 shows the estimated captures for different<br />

components <strong>of</strong> the waste stream. 852 These are greater in the commercial stream for<br />

all materials other than textiles (see Table 51-1 and Table 51-2). These figures are<br />

shown diagrammatically in Figure 51-3 and Figure 51-4.<br />

Table 51-1: Quantities and Captures for Recovery, Household <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Total Total Landfilled Landfilled % Recovered Recovered %<br />

Paper 385,074 187,350 48.7 197,724 51.3<br />

Glass 131,300 38,759 29.5 92,540 70.5<br />

Plastic 195,881 153,662 78.4 42,219 21.6<br />

Ferrous 23,590 17,188 72.9 6,402 27.1<br />

Aluminium 22,213 16,876 76 5,337 24<br />

Other Metals 2,218 1,513 68.2 705 31.8<br />

Textiles 199,571 188,680 94.5 10,891 5.5<br />

Organics 444,579 406,182 91.4 38,397 8.6<br />

Wood 23,261 15,051 64.7 8,210 35.3<br />

Others 197,803 175,719 88.8 22,085 11.2<br />

Total Total<br />

1,625,490 1,200,980 1,200,980 73.9 73.9 424,510 424,510 26.1<br />

26.1<br />

Source: EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

What is striking, from the graphic representation, given the objectives <strong>of</strong> the Landfill<br />

Directive, is the fact that:<br />

1) The capture <strong>of</strong> the single largest stream in municipal waste – the organics – is<br />

very low, at around 9%. It seems quite likely that this is heavily concentrated on<br />

the garden waste fraction;<br />

2) Very large quantities <strong>of</strong> paper (and card) remain uncaptured, although capture<br />

rates are estimated as being above 50% in both streams; and<br />

852 A problem with this data appears to be the lack <strong>of</strong> correspondence between the assumed<br />

composition <strong>of</strong> waste in the EPA report, and the estimated composition <strong>of</strong> waste, as set out in the<br />

EPA’s <strong>Waste</strong> Characterisation Study. The composition <strong>of</strong> household waste in the EPA <strong>Waste</strong> report is<br />

not the same as the composition <strong>of</strong> household waste in the Characterisation Study. The way in which<br />

the data has been derived is worthy <strong>of</strong> some closer examination.<br />

699<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


3) Very large quantities <strong>of</strong> textiles remain uncaptured in the household waste<br />

stream.<br />

These streams are the key biodegradable municipal waste streams and policy clearly<br />

needs to be developed to ensure these materials are better captured.<br />

Table 51-2: Quantities and Captures for Recovery, Commercial <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Total Total Landfilled Landfilled Landfilled % Recovered Recovered %<br />

Paper 528,995 196,895 37.2 332,100 62.8<br />

Glass 51,255 9,316 18.2 41,939 81.8<br />

Plastic 92,879 70,093 75.5 22,786 24.5<br />

Ferrous 70,768 3,889 5.5 66,878 94.5<br />

Aluminium 10,290 8,003 77.8 2,286 22.2<br />

Other Metals 4,421 2,531 57.3 1,890 42.7<br />

Textiles 45,353 45,353 100 0 0<br />

Organics 473,844 433,624 91.5 40,220 8.5<br />

Wood 217,413 1,942 0.9 215,471 99.1<br />

Others 53,857 42,171 78.3 11,686 21.7<br />

Total Total Total<br />

1,549,075 813,818 813,818 52.5 52.5 735,257 735,257 47.5<br />

47.5<br />

Source: EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

Figure 51-3: Materials Captured (recovered) and Uncaptured (landfilled), Household<br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

Tonnes<br />

700<br />

500,000<br />

450,000<br />

400,000<br />

350,000<br />

300,000<br />

250,000<br />

200,000<br />

150,000<br />

100,000<br />

50,000<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

Paper Glass Plastic Ferrous Aluminium Other Metals Textiles Organics Wood Others<br />

Material<br />

Material Captured Material Uncaptured<br />

Source: EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.


Figure 51-4: Materials Captured (recovered) and Uncaptured (landfilled), Commercial<br />

<strong>Waste</strong><br />

Tonnes<br />

701<br />

600,000<br />

500,000<br />

400,000<br />

300,000<br />

200,000<br />

100,000<br />

0<br />

Paper Glass Plastic Ferrous Aluminium Other Metals Textiles Organics Wood Others<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Material<br />

Material Captured Material Uncaptured<br />

Source: EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

As an additional observation, the fraction termed ‘other’ includes the ‘fines’ fraction.<br />

The fines fraction is composed <strong>of</strong> waste which falls through a screen with 20mm<br />

mesh size. This material frequently contains significant quantities <strong>of</strong> food waste. A<br />

plot <strong>of</strong> the organic matter (as % dry matter) versus the moisture content <strong>of</strong> food waste<br />

indicates some correlation between the two, although a relatively weak one. Moisture<br />

content <strong>of</strong> fines averages around 50%, with several samples exceeding 60% moisture<br />

content. At the same time, organic matter content averages 50%, with several<br />

samples above 60% organic matter (as a proportion <strong>of</strong> dry matter). Our hypothesis<br />

would be that, as a conservative estimate, 50% <strong>of</strong> fines are composed <strong>of</strong> food waste<br />

or other putrescible material. 853 This would suggest that the estimated capture <strong>of</strong><br />

organics is overstated at present, and that the presence <strong>of</strong> food and grass clippings in<br />

the waste stream is underestimated because <strong>of</strong> the significance <strong>of</strong> fines in the waste<br />

853 It is increasingly common, in the context <strong>of</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> MBT facilities, to come across waste<br />

characterisation studies which incorporate a size assay element. This has helped to inform<br />

understanding <strong>of</strong> how to design facilities to extract ‘sub-streams’ <strong>of</strong> material. As a result, most facilities<br />

incorporating an anaerobic step employ a mesh size <strong>of</strong> around 40-80mm to seek to target a<br />

‘predominantly biodegradable’ fraction. This is because the putrescible wastes are mostly to be found<br />

in the ‘small size’ categories, including ‘fines’.


stream (estimated at 8% in the <strong>Waste</strong> Characterisation report carried out on behalf <strong>of</strong><br />

the EPA. 854)<br />

Finally, it is important to comment on why the commercial and household captures <strong>of</strong><br />

dry recyclables are so much higher than the capture <strong>of</strong> organics. In principle, the<br />

economics <strong>of</strong> both both the source separation <strong>of</strong> dry recyclables, and the collection and<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> source segregated organic materials, are driven by the avoided costs <strong>of</strong><br />

disposal. In principle, therefore, the two might be expected to develop in parallel.<br />

Clearly, this has not happened.<br />

One reason for this is that the separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste presumes the existence<br />

<strong>of</strong> a treatment facility which is capable <strong>of</strong> handling the materials as collected by the<br />

collecting entity. Not only does this require a degree <strong>of</strong> certainty in terms <strong>of</strong> the<br />

direction <strong>of</strong> travel in respect <strong>of</strong> separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste, but it also presumes<br />

that the approach to licensing facilities is not unduly onerous, and facilitates<br />

investment by developers <strong>of</strong> such facilities. It can be argued that the absence <strong>of</strong> any<br />

certainty in terms <strong>of</strong> the direction <strong>of</strong> travel <strong>of</strong> policy – at least until recently – has<br />

made it difficult to justify investments in both additional collection infrastructure, and<br />

the treatment <strong>of</strong> collected materials. 855 The matter <strong>of</strong> treatment <strong>of</strong> organic waste has<br />

been further hindered by a lack <strong>of</strong> clarity over the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Animal Byproducts<br />

Regulation in Ireland, though this now shows signs <strong>of</strong> being resolved (see<br />

Annex 37.0).<br />

51.2.1 Potential Treatment Capacity for Organic <strong>Waste</strong>s from the Municipal<br />

Stream<br />

A report by InterTradeIreland suggests that on the island <strong>of</strong> Ireland (i.e. including<br />

Northern Ireland), capacity at licensed and permitted sites which have the capability<br />

for treating animal by-products is <strong>of</strong> the order 718,000 tonnes, <strong>of</strong> which, facilities <strong>of</strong><br />

capacity around 313,000 tonnes are currently operational. These facilities have<br />

around 135,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> spare capacity.<br />

It is estimated that <strong>of</strong> the unbuilt, but licensed / permitted capacity, around 235,000<br />

tonnes could be built by early 2010. In addition, there are sites in the planning<br />

process at present. 856<br />

The picture is not completely clear from this report regarding the situation in the<br />

Republic <strong>of</strong> Ireland. Our own brief attempt to generate relevant data suggests that<br />

currently operational capacity for facilities capable <strong>of</strong> treating animal by-products is <strong>of</strong><br />

the order 86,000 tonnes, but that there is ‘latent’ capacity which may be <strong>of</strong> the order<br />

854 RPS (2009) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Characterisation Surveys 2008, Final Report for the EPA, March<br />

2009.<br />

855 This review clearly has not helped add to the certainty, and one aim <strong>of</strong> the review must be to give<br />

greater certainty to investors regarding the nature <strong>of</strong> alternatives to landfill required, and regarding the<br />

flow <strong>of</strong> materials into non-landfill facilities without at the same time undermining the desirability <strong>of</strong><br />

delivering on high recycling rates.<br />

856 InterTradeIreland (2009) Market Report on the Composting and Anaerobic Digestion Sectors,<br />

Report for Cre and WRAP, May 2009.<br />

702<br />

29/09/09


200,000 tonnes, though some <strong>of</strong> this may be being earmarked for the biological<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> residual waste (i.e. MBT facilities). This would only become clear with a<br />

more thorough investigation. However, the suggestion is that if market conditions<br />

improve, that capacity might be developed relatively swiftly. This is important for<br />

reasons which will be explained below.<br />

Some stakeholders have mentioned the amount <strong>of</strong> capacity available at rendering<br />

plants in Ireland. It is far from clear to us that rendering plants would be suitable for<br />

dealing with much <strong>of</strong> the biodegradable waste in Ireland. Rendering may be<br />

appropriate for dealing with some biowastes, notably animal parts, but the process<br />

would give rise to residues requiring subsequent treatment. The EPA, on the other<br />

hand, appears to be confident that rendering facilities could deal with biowaste which<br />

is collected, at least in the short term.<br />

One clear problem for Ireland, facing up to the urgency <strong>of</strong> the current situation, is that<br />

as collectors roll out biowaste collection infrastructure, the demand for biowaste<br />

treatment infrastructure has the potential to exceed supply. This could lead to<br />

relatively high prices (composting gate fees are already estimated to be at high levels<br />

by European standards) in the short-term whilst the infrastructure develops. The<br />

availability <strong>of</strong> capacity at rendering plants would, therefore, be useful as much from<br />

the perspective <strong>of</strong> setting a price ceiling as from the desirability <strong>of</strong> the treatment per<br />

se.<br />

51.3 Treatment <strong>of</strong> Residual Municipal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

As regards the treatment <strong>of</strong> residual municipal waste, there is very little by way <strong>of</strong><br />

facilities currently operating in Ireland. There are facilities in development and others<br />

with planning permission and permits already in place.<br />

51.3.1 Thermal Treatment<br />

The last meaningful review <strong>of</strong> the status <strong>of</strong> Regional <strong>Waste</strong> Plans was provided in<br />

‘Taking Stock and Moving Forward’. 857 As <strong>of</strong> the end <strong>of</strong> 2003/early 2004, the<br />

document reported that <strong>of</strong> the ten regions, all but two provided for thermal treatment<br />

in their plans, though Wicklow indicated a preference to use capacity developed<br />

elsewhere. Of the two without thermal treatment in their plans, one <strong>of</strong> them, Cork, is a<br />

region in which proposals for such a facility are already advanced.<br />

Since the publication <strong>of</strong> ‘Taking Stock’, many Regions have revisited their Regional<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Plans. A recent report suggests, however, that only Donegal, Wicklow and<br />

Kildare do not recommend the use <strong>of</strong> thermal treatment within their Regional <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Plans, but these regions suggest that they will look at developments in neighbouring<br />

regions. 858<br />

857 DoEHLG (2004) Taking Stock and Moving Forward, April 2004.<br />

858 Fehily Timoney and Co (2008) Critical Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Potential for Mechanical Biological Treatment<br />

for Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Volume 2, Research Report for the EPA, September 2008.<br />

703<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


In respect <strong>of</strong> incineration, the EPA notes: 859<br />

704<br />

29/09/09<br />

In November 2005, the EPA granted licences1 for two commercial incinerators.<br />

The licences provide for the operation <strong>of</strong> waste incineration facilities by<br />

Indaver Ireland at Carranstown, Co. Meath (W0167-01) and Ringaskiddy, Co.<br />

Cork (W0186-01). In November 2008, the EPA granted a licence for a third<br />

municipal waste incinerator at Ringsend in Dublin (W0232-01). None <strong>of</strong> these<br />

facilities are operating as <strong>of</strong> end-2008 and only the Carranstown facility has<br />

commenced construction.<br />

The capacity <strong>of</strong> these facilities is 150,000 tonnes in the case <strong>of</strong> Carranstown,<br />

600,000 tonnes in the case <strong>of</strong> Dublin and 200,000 tonnes in Cork (<strong>of</strong> which half<br />

might be used for municipal waste). 860 The South East region is also in the midst <strong>of</strong><br />

procuring treatment capacity. The original plan in the South East proposed a facility<br />

limited to 150,000 tonnes.<br />

Other regions have expressed intentions to develop incineration (or other thermal<br />

treatment facilities) and some have set recovery targets:<br />

� Connaught 33% <strong>of</strong> all waste<br />

� Clare / Kerry / Limerick 41% <strong>of</strong> household and commercial waste<br />

� Midlands 58% <strong>of</strong> household waste<br />

30% C&I waste<br />

The EPA also notes that in 2007, 107,205 tonnes <strong>of</strong> non-hazardous waste was<br />

reported by recovery operators to have been used for combustion (see Table 51-3). Of<br />

this, some 32,695 tonnes were exported for use as a fuel.<br />

Table 51-3: Non-hazardous <strong>Waste</strong> Used as a Fuel, 2007<br />

Material Material<br />

Total Total Tonnes Tonnes<br />

Of Of Of which, which, which, packaging<br />

packaging<br />

Wood 71,774 24,781<br />

Refuse derived fuel 32,695 6,963<br />

Edible oil and fats 2,736<br />

Total Total<br />

107,205 107,205<br />

31,744<br />

31,744<br />

Source: EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

51.3.2 Cement Kilns<br />

Consultations have highlighted that Lagan Cement is also already co-incinerating<br />

Solid Recovered Fuel at its facility following a review <strong>of</strong> its PPC license. Approximately<br />

50,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> SRF are likely to be utilised at the facility on an annual basis. Along<br />

with the other cement companies (Irish Cement and Quinn Cement) the Irish cement<br />

industry is likely to have a combined capability to receive SRF <strong>of</strong> around 140,000<br />

859 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

860 Indaver is applying for a review <strong>of</strong> the Carranstown licence to increase the capacity <strong>of</strong> the waste-toenergy<br />

plant from 150,000 tonnes per annum to 200,000 tonnes per annum. The Carranstown facility<br />

commenced construction in September 2008.


tonnes early in 2010, and as much as 280,000 tonnes per annum later in the year.<br />

The SRF would be displacing coal at Lagan cement and Quinn Cement, and petcoke<br />

at the Irish Cement facilities. Studies suggest that this will make the overall<br />

environmental effect<br />

Given the fuel specification is <strong>of</strong> the order 16MJ/kg and above, with defined limits on<br />

ash content, chlorine, moisture and heavy metals, mixed residual MSW is likely to<br />

require pre-treatment so that the 280,000 tonnes capacity is likely to be derived from<br />

a larger quantity <strong>of</strong> residual MSW. The exact quantity depends upon the waste<br />

stream, but the quantity might be expected to be no less than 300,000 tonnes, and<br />

as much as 600,000 tonnes.<br />

The degree to which cement kilns might deal with biodegradable material might<br />

appear, at first glance, to have been compromised by the EPA’s specification <strong>of</strong> pertreatment<br />

in that this tends to suggest that SRF should be derived principally from<br />

non-biodegradable waste streams. The Guidance document appears to push MBT<br />

suppliers towards a ‘splitting approach’ since landfill site operators would, in<br />

principle, not be allowed to accept waste at landfills without it having been dealt with<br />

in such a way. 861 However, we are informed by the EPA that this arises from a too<br />

literal interpretation <strong>of</strong> the document, and that in principle, the approach to<br />

generating SRF is not constrained.<br />

51.3.3 Mechanical Biological Treatment<br />

Regarding mechanical biological treatment (MBT) facilities, this is rightly described in<br />

a STRIVE report as being in its infancy in Ireland. 862 The report states that at least two<br />

facilities export a refuse-derived fuel (RDF) for thermal treatment abroad. There are<br />

also some facilities which have potential to be deployed as MBT facilities, some <strong>of</strong><br />

these described in a 2008 report. 863 These may be capable <strong>of</strong> delivering reductions in<br />

the biodegradability <strong>of</strong> waste which they handle, so contributing to meeting targets in<br />

due course.<br />

It remains to be seen how the EPA’s Guidance on Pre-treatment and Residuals<br />

<strong>Management</strong> will affect the development <strong>of</strong> MBT in Ireland. Discussions with EPA<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficials suggest that the Guidance Document is not a full reflection <strong>of</strong> the way in<br />

which the Pre-treatment requirement will be implemented. 864<br />

861 EPA (2009) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> - Pre-treatment and Residuals <strong>Management</strong>: An EPA Technical<br />

Guidance Document, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

862 Fehily Timoney & Company / Veolia Environmental Services / Ramboll (2008) Critical Analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

the Potential for Mechanical Biological Treatment for Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Volume 2, Report for<br />

the Environmental Protection Agency, September 2008.<br />

863 Eunomia with Tobin (2008) Meeting Ireland’s <strong>Waste</strong> Targets: The Role <strong>of</strong> MBT, Final Report to<br />

Greenstar.<br />

864 If one takes the Guidance at face value, then it would difficult to understand why the EPA made the<br />

decisions which it appeared to have made. In addition, the Guidance document does not give sufficient<br />

detail concerning how the Guidance is to be operationalised, and there are several decisions made<br />

where the justification is through appeal to the need to demonstrate BAT, though this is not clearly<br />

705<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


51.4 Existing Targets<br />

Several targets apply to Ireland through the application <strong>of</strong> EU legislation, whilst others<br />

have been set at the national level in support <strong>of</strong> the delivery <strong>of</strong> EU targets. A brief<br />

review <strong>of</strong> these is <strong>of</strong>fered below.<br />

51.4.1 Landfill Directive<br />

In 1995, Ireland landfilled 1.29 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste<br />

(BMW). 865 The Landfill Directive targets imply, therefore, that:<br />

706<br />

• No more than 967 thousand tonnes <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste may be<br />

landfilled in 2010;<br />

• No more than 645 thousand tonnes <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste may be<br />

landfilled in 2013; and<br />

• No more than 451 thousand tonnes <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste may be<br />

landfilled in 2016.<br />

The targets imply successive reductions in absolute quantities <strong>of</strong> BMW being<br />

landfilled. For Ireland, the most worrying fact is that despite improvements in<br />

recycling <strong>of</strong> household and commercial waste, the rate <strong>of</strong> growth in BMW has nullified<br />

these efforts in terms <strong>of</strong> their contribution to Landfill Directive targets. The country<br />

appears to be ‘running to stand still’, with landfilled BMW still higher in 2007 than it<br />

was in 1995 (see Figure 51-5).<br />

This re-iterates the points made earlier concerning:<br />

� the need to be clear about whether what is classified as commercial waste<br />

really is commercial waste. The growth in what is reported as BMW, and the<br />

actual quantity <strong>of</strong> BMW may be two completely different things. 866 Given the<br />

potential ramifications (in terms <strong>of</strong> cost and timing) <strong>of</strong> over-estimating MSW,<br />

and hence (through applying composition data derived from Characterisation<br />

Studies related to specific waste streams), BMW, some detailed investigations,<br />

and potentially, even measures to keep waste streams separate, might be<br />

desirable; and<br />

� the need to step up activity in respect <strong>of</strong> source separation <strong>of</strong> the major<br />

components <strong>of</strong> biowaste.<br />

elaborated. The EPA is clearly – on the basis <strong>of</strong> communications with them - confident that the<br />

Guidance will achieve what it sets out to. However, confidence in this regard might have been<br />

enhanced had the document been clearer on a number <strong>of</strong> matters which are <strong>of</strong> material significance.<br />

865 EPA (2003) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2001, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

866 The EPA recognises that the basis for understanding the composition <strong>of</strong> BMW in the waste stream<br />

is not ideal from the perspective <strong>of</strong> what is reported as municipal waste by landfill operators. According<br />

to personal communications, the supposition is that ‘genuine’ municipal waste is frequently mixed with<br />

other materials, such as C&D waste, before being sent to landfill, where all the material is declared as<br />

MSW.<br />

29/09/09


We discuss the matters further below.<br />

Figure 51-5: Evolution in BMW Managed and BMW Landfilled<br />

Tonnes<br />

707<br />

2,500,000<br />

2,000,000<br />

1,500,000<br />

1,000,000<br />

500,000<br />

0<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007<br />

Source: EPA National <strong>Waste</strong> Reports.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Year<br />

BMW Landfilled BMW Managed<br />

Note: Managed BMW is interpolated for years between 1995 and 2001. BMW<br />

landfilled is interpolated for 1996, 1997, 1999 and 2000. In both cases, evolution<br />

between known data points is assumed to be linear.<br />

51.4.2 Existing National Targets<br />

The key targets at the national level in Ireland are found essentially in two<br />

documents:<br />

� Changing Our Ways – this document contains the key targets for Irish waste<br />

management; 867 and<br />

� The National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy (NBS), which identifies the ‘gap’<br />

which must be closed if Ireland is to meet Landfill Directive targets. 868<br />

However, it is acknowledged that this ‘gap’ may change as projections change.<br />

The ‘gap’ is derived from the Landfill Directive Article 5 targets and the<br />

projections for waste growth.<br />

867 DoELG (1998) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Changing our Ways, September 1998.<br />

868 DoELG (2006) National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy, April 2006.


51.4.2.1 ‘Changing Our Ways’<br />

Changing Our Ways set out the following quantitative targets <strong>of</strong> relevance to the<br />

Landfill Directive, to be achieved over a 15-year period (i.e. to 2013): 869<br />

708<br />

1. a diversion <strong>of</strong> 50% <strong>of</strong> overall household waste away from landfill;<br />

2. a minimum 65% reduction in biodegradable wastes consigned to landfill;,<br />

3. the development <strong>of</strong> waste recovery facilities employing environmentally<br />

beneficial technologies, as an alternative to landfill, including the development<br />

<strong>of</strong> composting and other feasible biological treatment facilities capable <strong>of</strong><br />

treating up to 300,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste per annum,<br />

4. recycling <strong>of</strong> 35% <strong>of</strong> municipal waste,<br />

5. recycling at least 50% <strong>of</strong> C&D waste within a five year period, with a<br />

progressive increase to at least 85% over fifteen years,<br />

6. an 80% reduction in methane emissions from landfill, which will make a useful<br />

contribution to meeting Ireland's international obligations.<br />

With the exception <strong>of</strong> target 2, there is little by way <strong>of</strong> supporting rationale or evidence<br />

provided to justify the choice <strong>of</strong> these particular targets. In the case <strong>of</strong> target 2, there<br />

does not appear to be monitoring <strong>of</strong> progress towards this target (which covers all<br />

waste, not just biodegradable municipal waste, which is monitored).<br />

These targets remained unchanged in a 2002 policy document. 870 In addition there<br />

was a stated aim <strong>of</strong> recovering 50% <strong>of</strong> packaging waste by 2005 (which follows from<br />

the Packaging Directive).<br />

The 35% recycling target, which had been regarded as ‘particularly challenging’ as<br />

late as 2004, 871 was more or less achieved by 2005, illustrating the rapidity <strong>of</strong><br />

progress, but also, the scope for further increases in recycling. The recovery rate<br />

reported by the EPA (which approximates very closely to a recycling rate) was 36.5%<br />

in 2007. 872<br />

As suggested above, precisely because Ireland’s definition <strong>of</strong> municipal waste<br />

includes commercial waste, the target might have been made somewhat easier to<br />

achieve than it might have been in countries where the definition <strong>of</strong> municipal waste<br />

is more closely aligned with household waste (given that much commercial waste<br />

arises in relatively clean streams <strong>of</strong> material, notably paper and card). This may<br />

explain why progress on recycling has been quicker than expected. At the same time,<br />

869 DoELG (1998) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Changing our Ways, September 1998.<br />

870 DoELG (2002) Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>: Delivering Change, March 2002.<br />

871 DoEHLG (2004) Managing <strong>Waste</strong>: Taking Stock & Moving Forward, April 2004.<br />

872 EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

29/09/09


as was made clear above, the inclusion <strong>of</strong> commercial waste in the definition <strong>of</strong><br />

municipal waste makes Landfill Directive targets more difficult to meet.<br />

51.4.2.2 National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy<br />

The National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy (NBS) sets out a range <strong>of</strong> ‘targets’. We<br />

use the term in parentheses since it is not always clear whether these really are<br />

targets or not, or at least, who the targets are to fall upon. They have the character<br />

more <strong>of</strong> calculations and projections as to ‘what might be required’ to meet the<br />

Landfill Directive under a particular set <strong>of</strong> assumptions. Targets are set for particular<br />

actors to achieve, but it is not always clear who has responsibility for meeting a given<br />

target from the document, still less, what might be the implications <strong>of</strong> failure to<br />

deliver these.<br />

Amongst these assumptions are that municipal waste generation will first <strong>of</strong> all stop<br />

growing, and then reverse, as a so-called waste reduction factor <strong>of</strong> 3% is applied from<br />

2005, rising to 6% by 2016. The projection is shown in Figure 51-6 below. This<br />

projection is important for the analysis since it establishes the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the<br />

expected performance gap.<br />

Figure 51-6: Projections for BMW Generation and Quantity Landfilled<br />

Source: DoEHLG (2006) National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy, April 2006.<br />

Second, the assumption implicit in the calculation <strong>of</strong> recycling rates is that the<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> commercial and household waste in municipal waste remains constant<br />

for the period to 2016. It clearly has not been constant thus far, and no justification is<br />

<strong>of</strong>fered for the assumption.<br />

The report sets targets for managing biodegradable waste in ways other than landfill<br />

as follows:<br />

709<br />

• 2010 required 1,412,083<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


710<br />

• 2013 required 1,729,585<br />

• 2016 required 1,817,262<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> what this might mean and for whom, the report states:<br />

29/09/09<br />

The assessment <strong>of</strong> capacity requirements, as indicated in Table 3.2, for<br />

alternative treatment methods to cater for the diversion <strong>of</strong> biodegradable<br />

municipal waste in the years 2010, 2013 and 2016 represents the national<br />

position. The various waste management planning regions / counties should<br />

assess their individual needs for BMW management. This approach will<br />

enable the gap or ‘indicative target diversion capacity’ for each region /<br />

county to be outlined.<br />

Targets were set for recycling <strong>of</strong> municipal waste paper and cardboard. These are set<br />

in terms <strong>of</strong> the capture <strong>of</strong> paper and cardboard:<br />

� 45% for households and 61% for commerce in 2010, corresponding to 55% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW;<br />

� 55% for households and 71% for commerce in 2013, corresponding to 65% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW; and<br />

� 60% for households and 73% for commerce in 2016, corresponding to 67% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW.<br />

Targets were set for home composting, the aim being to ensure this takes place at<br />

20% <strong>of</strong> urban households and 55% <strong>of</strong> rural households – equivalent to some 35% <strong>of</strong><br />

all households - by 2010. It was anticipated that potential yield from this would be<br />

between 10% to 12% <strong>of</strong> available organic waste in the years 2010 and 2016.<br />

For organic waste, the targets were:<br />

� 40% coverage for households and 60% coverage for commerce in 2010 at an<br />

estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 45% to 60% respectively, corresponding to 25% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall organic waste generation within BMW;<br />

� 45% coverage for households and 70% coverage for commerce in 2013 at an<br />

estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 50% to 65% respectively, corresponding to 33% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall organic waste generation within BMW; and<br />

� 50% coverage for households and 70% coverage for commerce in 2016 at an<br />

estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 55% to 70% respectively, corresponding to 36% <strong>of</strong><br />

overall organic waste generation within BMW.<br />

The above targets were assumed, in the NBS, to lead to a requirement for residual<br />

BMW treatment capacity as follows:<br />

� an estimated 308,904 tonnes <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment will be necessary in<br />

2010;<br />

� an estimated 438,190 tonnes <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment will be necessary in<br />

2013; and<br />

� an estimated 499,762 tonnes <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment will be necessary in<br />

2016.<br />

These figures are couched as ‘targets’, and extraordinarily precise ones as that.


51.4.2.3 Comment on Targets<br />

A concern with the targets from ‘Changing Our Ways’ would be that because the<br />

targets which were set were not given detailed consideration, it could not have been<br />

entirely clear which targets were truly challenging and which were not. Whatever the<br />

source <strong>of</strong> the caution being exercised, it is worth considering the drawbacks <strong>of</strong> a lack<br />

<strong>of</strong> ambition where target setting is concerned. Ireland is, in some ways, fortunate (in<br />

other ways, rather less so – see below) that major infrastructure provision has not<br />

progressed as quickly as might have been hoped. If regions and local authorities had<br />

instated infrastructure on the basis that such recycling rates really were ‘challenging’,<br />

they might have seriously over-provided capacity for residual waste treatment and<br />

infrastructure, though much would depend upon the growth rate they chose to base<br />

capacity estimates upon.<br />

This has been the experience with many local authorities in England following the<br />

publication <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy 2000, which set a household waste recycling target <strong>of</strong><br />

33% for 2015. The target in the most recent strategy, <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy for England<br />

2007, is 50%. In the interim period, many local authorities have procured<br />

infrastructure which will make it difficult for them to justify the expenditure on source<br />

separation to achieve recycling rates <strong>of</strong> 50% when costs have already been sunk into<br />

residual waste treatment infrastructure. Essentially, the experience <strong>of</strong> England is<br />

similar to that <strong>of</strong> Ireland – that ‘challenging’ recycling rates have been met and<br />

surpassed far faster, and far more easily, than was thought possible. English data<br />

shows the recycling rate for household waste in England was 34.5% for 2007/8,<br />

implying the target set in 2000, to be met by 2015, had already been met. 873<br />

As regards the NBS targets, the first point to make is that these are not entirely clear.<br />

They are buried within a lengthy document, and it is not clear what ‘targets’ really are<br />

targets, and who has to meet them. The NBS repeatedly makes reference to the<br />

regions and their plans. It suggests that they have to meet these targets, but it is not<br />

clear how the regions should construe the targets.<br />

Regarding national diversion targets, the NBS states:<br />

711<br />

These national targets for BMW diversion for the years 2010, 2013 and 2016<br />

represent the national position. As indicated in Section 3.4 <strong>of</strong> the Strategy, the<br />

various waste management planning regions / counties should assess their<br />

individual needs for BMW management in order to obtain an ‘indicative target<br />

diversion capacity’. Regions / counties must then decide how their <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans can address these requirements.<br />

These figures should be kept under continuous review and updated regularly<br />

by each region / county, in order to ensure that sufficient capacity is available<br />

to facilitate the achievement <strong>of</strong> the required BMW diversion targets.<br />

Regarding the targets for residual waste, it states:<br />

873 Statistics from <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment Food and Rural Affairs (Defra).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


712<br />

29/09/09<br />

There will be a certain amount <strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste for which it<br />

is not feasible to achieve a sufficient level <strong>of</strong> segregated collection to satisfy<br />

the required landfill diversion targets. Accordingly, there will also be a need to<br />

collect this material as residual BMW and to provide treatment – either<br />

thermally or through some form <strong>of</strong> stabilisation – to reduce the biological<br />

activity to imperceptible levels and thereby ensure achievement <strong>of</strong> the<br />

mandatory diversion targets.<br />

Regions / counties must decide how their <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans can<br />

address these requirements.<br />

Finally, it states:<br />

Each <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan should meet the targets <strong>of</strong> this Strategy,<br />

identifying the combination <strong>of</strong> collections and treatment types that suit local<br />

conditions and objectives. Each Plan should be reviewed on that basis.<br />

Each Annual Implementation Report to be prepared by local authorities on the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan, as required under Key Point<br />

13 <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Taking Stock and Moving Forward, should record<br />

progress made in relation to the National Strategy on Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong><br />

over the previous year. The format to be followed in the Annual<br />

Implementation Report will be specified in a Circular letter issued to all local<br />

authorities by the DoEHLG.<br />

What might not be clear to any <strong>of</strong> the planning regions is which targets really apply to<br />

them, and how should they implement the requirements to deliver the NBS? Do they<br />

all know, for example, how much BMW they should consider they were landfilling in<br />

1995? What is their ‘quota’ <strong>of</strong> the national allowance? If this is not known, how could<br />

the relevant calculations be performed? 874 Do the BMW projections imply ‘targets’?<br />

Who do any <strong>of</strong> the targets actually fall upon? If some local authorities do not collect<br />

any waste, is it reasonable to assume that they will take up the challenge <strong>of</strong> such<br />

targets seriously? Would it be appropriate to apply sanctions to them if they don’t,<br />

and if sanctions are not to be applied, how realistic is it to expect targets to be met?<br />

In short, whilst the document seeks to chart a way forward for Ireland to meet Landfill<br />

Directive targets, and whilst it contains some interesting targets in terms <strong>of</strong> home<br />

composting and source separation, the manner in which these should cascade down<br />

(to the regional level) is not always clear. The presumption appears to have been that<br />

the regions will implement these, even though the regions simply do not have the<br />

competence to deliver – in and <strong>of</strong> themselves – the outcomes.<br />

Interestingly, most <strong>of</strong> the Annual Implementation Reports for the Regional <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans make little or no reference to targets that the NBS suggests they<br />

should be implementing. Since there are very few Annual Implementation Reports<br />

which have been produced by the Regions, and since the NBS was completed only<br />

after most <strong>of</strong> the Regional <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans were updated, then it would<br />

874 The Draft NBS did actually apportion the national allowance to the regional level, which would have<br />

been a starting point for implementation at the regional level.


seem that there is little or no basis to be confident that the Regions are seeking to<br />

implement the NBS as it stands.<br />

In summary (see also Annex 59.0):<br />

713<br />

� Some <strong>of</strong> the older targets were lacking in ambition. In particular, the recycling<br />

targets have probably been met substantially as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the hike in<br />

landfill gate fees which has increased the benefits associated with avoided<br />

disposal. All <strong>of</strong> the targets should probably have been revisited at the latest in<br />

2002, long after the full shape <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive was widely known.<br />

Other targets have lacked force – and would probably not be met in the<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> further significant policy change - since there has been no<br />

mechanism to implement them. The presumption has been that the regions<br />

will integrate these into their plans. However, the regions have generally<br />

lacked the competence and tools to ensure that these targets are met, whilst<br />

no sanction is on the horizon to incentivise compliance on their behalf; and<br />

� The newer targets in the NBS – like many <strong>of</strong> the older targets – are not<br />

addressed at anyone in particular. Since no sanctions are to be applied<br />

(because it is not clear to whom the targets attach, and hence, who would be<br />

the subject <strong>of</strong> any sanction), then it seems reasonable to question whether<br />

any targets set out in the NBS will be met, let alone, how they would be<br />

considered by the Regions. The lack <strong>of</strong> any ‘cascading downwards’ <strong>of</strong> the<br />

targets is effectively confirmed through the absence <strong>of</strong> evidence that Regions<br />

have adapted their <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans to align them with the NBS<br />

(since, presumably, had they done so, this would have been made clear in<br />

Annual Implementation Reports, which few regions have actually prepared).<br />

51.5 Current and Proposed <strong>Policy</strong> Measures<br />

As regards residual waste treatment, there are no targets which fall upon<br />

organisations who might be deemed appropriate addressees for such targets. There<br />

are three policy instruments in the <strong>of</strong>fing which may serve to enhance the prospects<br />

<strong>of</strong> Landfill Directive targets being met.<br />

51.5.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Levy<br />

Following a Consultation on a <strong>Waste</strong> Levy, a Regulatory Impact Analysis has been<br />

developed for both a levy on plastic bags, and ‘a levy on certain waste facilities’. 875<br />

The principal objective <strong>of</strong> the proposed <strong>Waste</strong> Facility Levy (WFL) is to support the<br />

Government’s goal <strong>of</strong> meeting the biodegradable municipal waste diversion targets<br />

under the EU Landfill Directive. Furthermore, it was a defined constraint <strong>of</strong> the RIA<br />

that the WFL should be structured such that, in accordance with the commitment<br />

outlined in the Programme for Government (2007), the Landfill Levy will not be<br />

altered in such a way as to give competitive advantage to incineration. Thus the WFL<br />

875 AP EnvEcon (forthcoming) Regulatory Impact Analysis on Proposed Legislation to Increase Levies<br />

on Shopping Bags and Certain <strong>Waste</strong> Facilities, Final Report.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


is proposed not to be set at a level that represents environmental costs <strong>of</strong> each<br />

option, as per the original intention <strong>of</strong>, for example, the UK’s Landfill Tax, but primarily<br />

with a focus on the distinct policy goal <strong>of</strong> encouraging development <strong>of</strong> alternatives to<br />

landfill, without giving competitive advantage to incineration.<br />

Regarding financial costs, the RIA states: 876<br />

714<br />

The model assumed marginal costs (excluding levies) for the alternative<br />

treatments as follows:<br />

29/09/09<br />

� Landfill €50 per tonne<br />

� Incineration €105 per tonne<br />

� MBT Medium €110 per tonne<br />

� MBT High €120 per tonne<br />

This means that the model assumes that these cost levels are required to operate<br />

the treatment options. If tariffs are higher than these costs, owners will receive a<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it higher than necessary. If tariffs are lower than these costs, owners will have<br />

a financial loss.<br />

The RIA effectively assumes that landfill operators are generating significant rents<br />

from their activities, and that levy increases might have the effect <strong>of</strong> squeezing these<br />

rents, but with gate fees, as a consequence, rising by a figure which is below that <strong>of</strong><br />

the levy itself.<br />

The RIA proposes the following levy structure:<br />

The recommendation <strong>of</strong> the RIA with respect to the WFL levy is that an<br />

announcement and commitment to the following tariff increases is proposed.<br />

An increase in the existing levy on landfill from €20 in 2008 to €40 in 2010<br />

and €75 in 2011. A levy on incineration <strong>of</strong> €22 from 2011. No levy for the<br />

landfill <strong>of</strong> suitably stabilised biowaste from 2010.<br />

It also proposed a maximum levy for landfill <strong>of</strong> €85 per tonne, for incineration <strong>of</strong> €45<br />

per tonne, and <strong>of</strong> €20 per tonne for stabilized biowaste.<br />

The study suggests that with this levy, Landfill Directive targets may be met by 2014-<br />

2015. This reflects the sorts <strong>of</strong> lead time expected in terms <strong>of</strong> investment decisions<br />

and developing and commissioning <strong>of</strong> facilities:<br />

Specifically, the lead time for investment decisions, the time required from the<br />

decision to having an operational plant and the speed with which investors<br />

decide to invest. The <strong>Department</strong> can influence this schedule by providing<br />

clear information about future developments <strong>of</strong> policies and by actions to<br />

diminish procedure time for the setup <strong>of</strong> new waste treatment technology<br />

capacity.<br />

876 AP EnvEcon (forthcoming) Regulatory Impact Analysis on Proposed Legislation to Increase Levies<br />

on Shopping Bags and Certain <strong>Waste</strong> Facilities, Final Report.


It acknowledges the role <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> potential supplementary measures in<br />

reducing the level <strong>of</strong> BMW sent to landfill and accelerating progress toward the BMW<br />

diversion targets, including:<br />

715<br />

accelerated planning for MBT facilities, minimum standards for MBT waste,<br />

support <strong>of</strong> composting initiatives, the role <strong>of</strong> incineration and increased<br />

coverage <strong>of</strong> pay by unit and ‘three-bin’ systems nationally.<br />

51.5.2 MSW - Pre-treatment and Residuals <strong>Management</strong><br />

In the Autumn <strong>of</strong> 2008, the EPA consulted upon a Technical Guidance Document<br />

entitled Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> - Pre-treatment and Residuals <strong>Management</strong>. 877 This<br />

was subsequently finalised and issued in June 2009. 878 The document suggests that<br />

the initiatives set out in the Guidance were intended to assist delivery <strong>of</strong> Ireland’s<br />

obligations under the EU <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive (2006/12/EC), the EU Landfill<br />

Directive (1999/31/EC), and the EU IPPC Directive (96/61/EC).<br />

Article 6 <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive requires, inter alia, that: 879<br />

Member States shall take measures in order that:<br />

(a) only waste that has been subject to treatment is landfilled. This<br />

provision may not apply to inert waste for which treatment is not<br />

technically feasible, nor to any other waste for which such treatment<br />

does not contribute to the objectives <strong>of</strong> this Directive, as set out in<br />

Article 1, by reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> the waste or the hazards to<br />

human health or the environment;<br />

For existing landfills, this was to take effect ten years after the publication date in the<br />

Official Journal, and for new landfills, the requirement took effect two years after its<br />

publication (i.e. on the date <strong>of</strong> transposition).<br />

Ireland’s approach to implementing this particular aspect <strong>of</strong> the Directive appears to<br />

have been somewhat delayed, particularly with regard to new landfills (for which the<br />

requirement to ensure that all waste landfilled has been pre-treated has been in<br />

place, formally, for eight years).<br />

The general thrust <strong>of</strong> the Pre-treatment Guidelines is positive. The Guidelines have<br />

ambitious objectives, effectively seeking to simultaneously:<br />

1. Comply with Article 6 <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive;<br />

2. Define BAT (though the term is not always applied in the conventional context);<br />

3. Deliver on Landfill Directive targets; and<br />

877 EPA (2008) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> - Pre-treatment and Residuals <strong>Management</strong>: An EPA Technical<br />

Guidance Document, Consultation Draft, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

878 EPA (2009) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> - Pre-treatment and Residuals <strong>Management</strong>: An EPA Technical<br />

Guidance Document, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

879 Council Directive 1999/31/EC <strong>of</strong> 26 April 1999 on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste Official Journal L 182 ,<br />

16/07/1999 pp. 1 – 19.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


716<br />

4. Effectively push for source separation <strong>of</strong> dry recyclables and biodegradable<br />

wastes.<br />

Particularly in respect <strong>of</strong> the last <strong>of</strong> these four points, it is not clear that the approach<br />

is the best mechanism. However, a reader <strong>of</strong> the document could be forgiven for<br />

thinking that the Guidance is effectively seeking to become ‘the measure’ by which<br />

Ireland meets its Landfill Directive targets in a fairly encompassing approach.<br />

In general, the Guidance is well intended. However, some issues remain outstanding<br />

on a reading <strong>of</strong> the document, including:<br />

� It lacks a detailed description <strong>of</strong> exactly what is expected to happen when the<br />

Guidance enters into force (as, in principle, it already has done). The date<br />

appears to have been set more with regard to the date set for complying with<br />

Article 6;<br />

� It stipulates some requirements which may deliver rather marginal benefit<br />

whilst imposing significant costs. Notable in this regard is the shift from a<br />

stability standard <strong>of</strong> 10 mg O2/g d.m. down to 7 mg O2/g d.m. The rationale<br />

given is that the approach is in line with continuous improvement outlined<br />

under BAT, but this does open up a range <strong>of</strong> questions regarding, for example,<br />

whether benefits are commensurate with costs, and how the same approach<br />

is translated to other facilities to which the requirement to demonstrate BAT<br />

also applies; 880<br />

� The targets for operators are set in terms <strong>of</strong> the proportion <strong>of</strong> BMW in MSW<br />

accepted at landfills, which might be an awkward way to specify the means to<br />

meet Landfill Directive targets unless the management <strong>of</strong> Irish waste in future<br />

follows the exact path which seems to have been modelled for it; and<br />

� It would seem to be incredibly difficult (perhaps impossible) to enforce the<br />

targets in a meaningful way, especially in the short term, and it is notable that<br />

no discussion on the issue <strong>of</strong> regulation and enforcement is to be found within<br />

the document.<br />

Notwithstanding the above comments, the EPA remains confident in its approach,<br />

and that the outcome will be satisfactory, but it is clear that the approach is very<br />

much in the development phase.<br />

880 In communications, the EPA expresses the view that this delivers additional reductions in<br />

biodegradability, which is no doubt true. The problem is that in order to meet the revised target, in<br />

principle, no change in ‘technique’ is necessarily required. Rather, the change is likely to lead to a<br />

considerable increase in the cost <strong>of</strong> achieving the standard through increasing the necessary retention<br />

time (although, no doubt, additional re-jigging <strong>of</strong> the facility could be made to achieve the higher<br />

standard, but mid-operation, this would be expensive). The extent to which this benefit could be said to<br />

be worth the additional cost <strong>of</strong> meeting the amended standard is not clear, but our own research<br />

suggests that the opposite is likely to be the case, possibly with a substantial cost for minimal benefit<br />

(see, for example, Eunomia (2008) ‘Biostabilisation’ <strong>of</strong> wastes: making the Case for a Differential Rate<br />

<strong>of</strong> Landfill Tax,<br />

http://www.eunomia.co.uk/shopimages/Eunomia%20Landfill%20Tax%20Paper%20Final.pdf )<br />

29/09/09


The proposed minimum pre-treatment obligations for waste intended to be accepted<br />

at MSW landfills are as follows (see Table 51-4).<br />

Table 51-4: Generic Facility Type – Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> Pre-treatment Obligations<br />

Principal Principal<br />

Principal Minimum Minimum Minimum pre-<br />

pre<br />

disposal disposal disposal route route<br />

route treatment treatment<br />

treatment<br />

required required<br />

required<br />

Landfill Landfill Landfill 1a. Separated<br />

at source.<br />

Diversion <strong>of</strong><br />

BMW from<br />

landfill disposal<br />

stream, (e.g.<br />

home<br />

composting, 2nd and 3rd bin,<br />

Civic Amenity<br />

Sites, etc.,)<br />

(see Note 1)<br />

and<br />

1b. Treatment<br />

<strong>of</strong> the<br />

biodegradable<br />

element <strong>of</strong><br />

‘black bin’ prelandfilling<br />

(See Note 2)<br />

WtE WtE<br />

WtE<br />

Incinerator ncinerator ncinerator<br />

717<br />

2. 2 Bin<br />

collection<br />

system<br />

3. Mechanical<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong><br />

black bin (in<br />

large urban<br />

centres)<br />

4. Source<br />

separated<br />

collection<br />

system<br />

5. Mechanical<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong><br />

incinerator<br />

ashes<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Required Required<br />

Required Date Date<br />

Date<br />

material material<br />

material<br />

diversion diversion<br />

diversion<br />

Biodegradables 2010, 2013 & 2016 for all<br />

landfills accepting MSW to the<br />

extent necessary to achieve the<br />

diversion obligations Note 3. Viz,<br />

� For report years 2010,<br />

2011 and 2012, a<br />

maximum <strong>of</strong> 40% by weight<br />

<strong>of</strong> MSW accepted at the<br />

landfill facility for disposal<br />

shall comprise BMW<br />

� For report years 2013,<br />

2014 and 2015, a<br />

maximum <strong>of</strong> 24% by weight<br />

<strong>of</strong> MSW accepted at the<br />

landfill facility for disposal<br />

shall comprise BMW;<br />

� For report years 2016,<br />

and subsequent years, a<br />

maximum <strong>of</strong> 15% by weight<br />

<strong>of</strong> MSW accepted at the<br />

landfill facility for disposal<br />

shall comprise BMW.<br />

Other<br />

16-7-09 for a landfill existing on<br />

recyclables 16-7-2001<br />

(glass, metals, 16-7-2001 for all other landfills<br />

plastics) (including major extensions)<br />

Metals By 1-1-2016<br />

SRF Note 4<br />

Other<br />

Biodegradables<br />

Other<br />

marketable<br />

recyclables<br />

Metals<br />

Other<br />

marketable<br />

recyclables<br />

Prior to commencement <strong>of</strong> any<br />

MSW incinerator<br />

Note 1: Where a 3 bin system is not available Treatment 1b will apply to the extent<br />

necessary to achieve an equivalent reduction in BMW.


Note 2: For the first two biodegradable waste diversion obligations (2010 & 2013), a<br />

national 3 bin system (including for catering/ commercial sources <strong>of</strong><br />

biowastes) will likely ensure, on its own, that the EU Landfill Directive<br />

diversion/treatment obligations are met through diversion from landfill <strong>of</strong> the<br />

biodegradable dry recyclables and the organics.<br />

Note 3: This will translate (approximately) to the tonnage <strong>of</strong> BMW accepted at<br />

landfills in 2010 being less than 25% <strong>of</strong> the tonnage MSW generated<br />

nationally; falling to < 15% in 2013, and < 9% in 2016.<br />

Note 4: SRF – Solid Recovered Fuel <strong>of</strong> defined specification for use as a fuel in coincineration<br />

plants, or other energy uses as may be approved, where<br />

available.<br />

Source: EPA (2009) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> - Pre-treatment and Residuals<br />

<strong>Management</strong>: An EPA Technical Guidance Document, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.<br />

In the medium- term, the establishment <strong>of</strong> a stability threshold is to be welcome.<br />

However, the Guidance document does not spell out unequivocally that the meeting<br />

<strong>of</strong> the stability criterion is intended to imply that the waste will be treated as ‘no<br />

longer biodegradable’ for the purposes <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive. Indeed, if such a<br />

measure had been considered earlier, this would have been the only measure<br />

required to implement the Landfill Directive, though other instruments would have<br />

been necessary to ensure that environmental benefits were realised through the<br />

approach. 881 In practice, it might be preferable for the Guidance to:<br />

718<br />

� Establish a pre-treatment requirement independently <strong>of</strong> the meeting <strong>of</strong> Landfill<br />

Directive targets, this being specified to allow the requirements to be easily<br />

met. 882 There does not, after all, appear to be any underpinning rationale for<br />

suggesting that what constitutes pre-treatment one day is not pre-treatment<br />

on another, but the Guidance appears to change the requirement for ‘pretreatment’<br />

in line with what is required to deliver Landfill Directive targets. This<br />

would allow the Government to discharge its obligations under Article 6 <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Landfill Directive; and<br />

� Establish a stability threshold for landfilling <strong>of</strong> all municipal waste, this<br />

requirement to be met not by 2016, but by 2013. Where, in a given region, the<br />

necessary infrastructure is absent, exemptions would be granted, but only<br />

where applied for in advance, and at additional cost to the holder <strong>of</strong> the waste.<br />

881 This measure alone would not necessarily have delivered the most desirable outcome. It might,<br />

however, have delivered on the Directive targets since it would have implied that no biodegradable<br />

municipal waste could be landfilled.<br />

882 The UK provides one example <strong>of</strong> a country which has defined pre-treatment very loosely. Pretreatment<br />

includes most activities which alter the nature <strong>of</strong> the waste, including sorting <strong>of</strong> a material<br />

from the waste stream. There are definitely drawbacks in such an approach, but the urgency <strong>of</strong><br />

meeting the Article 6 targets might suggest a similarly simple approach. In Scotland, the regulator<br />

effectively assumes that the pre-treatment requirements are met so that the measure implies very little<br />

for waste producers (though some collectors have used the requirements to encourage some<br />

customers to sort materials where they had not been doing so previously).<br />

29/09/09


719<br />

The introduction <strong>of</strong> this measure in 2013 would give greater certainty that<br />

targets under Article 5 <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive – especially for 2013, but also<br />

for 2016 - would be met.<br />

This sequencing would recognise the fact that in the short-term, the potential for<br />

radical change is limited, but that as soon as is prudent, the requirement to pre-treat<br />

waste to ensure that the required stability threshold is met is introduced.<br />

51.5.3 Statutory Instrument<br />

In August 2009, DoEHLG published a Draft <strong>of</strong> a Statutory Instrument the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Food <strong>Waste</strong>) Regulations 2009. Regulation 7 states:<br />

7. (1) Subject to paragraphs (3) and (4) and without prejudice to the power <strong>of</strong><br />

any local authority to provide for additional policy objectives under a relevant<br />

waste management plan or to apply more onerous conditions under a waste<br />

collection permit or under a waste presentation bye-law, a producer shall<br />

ensure, as a minimum, that -<br />

(a) food waste arising on the producer’s premises is source segregated<br />

and kept separate from non-biodegradable materials, other waste and<br />

contaminants, and<br />

(b) source segregated food waste arising on the producer’s premises is<br />

-<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

(i) collected by an authorised waste collector and transferred to<br />

an authorised biological treatment facility, or<br />

(ii) subjected to biological treatment in an authorised facility on<br />

the premises where the food waste was produced, or<br />

(iii) transferred directly by the producer to an authorised facility<br />

for the purposes <strong>of</strong> biological treatment, subject to the producer<br />

being able to produce satisfactory documentary evidence, in the<br />

reasonable opinion <strong>of</strong> the local authority, <strong>of</strong> the acceptance <strong>of</strong><br />

the food waste at the facility.<br />

For the purposes <strong>of</strong> this Regulation, producers are defined under Schedule 1 <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Draft Regulations.<br />

The Regulations are due to come into operation in January 2010, but the Regulations<br />

<strong>of</strong> greatest relevance (including Regulation 7) will take effect from 1 July 2010. These<br />

Regulations are clearly well-intended, but the challenge will be to ensure both that the<br />

roll-out <strong>of</strong> food waste collection is sufficiently rapid, and that the require treatment<br />

capacity will be in place. The latter is the more worrying. In this respect, it is worth<br />

noting that ‘biological treatment’ is defined as:<br />

“biological treatment”, , for the purposes <strong>of</strong> these regulations, refers to -<br />

(a) an aerobic process, or<br />

(b) an anaerobic process, or<br />

(c) any heat induced digestion process


720<br />

29/09/09<br />

used for the treatment <strong>of</strong> organic waste and which produces a stabilised<br />

output free <strong>of</strong> pathogens, which can be used as -<br />

- a soil fertiliser and conditioner,<br />

- a replacement for fossil fuel in energy production processes, or<br />

- as a feed constituent in food fed to animals.<br />

It seems clear that this is designed, in part, to facilitate inclusion <strong>of</strong> rendering. If,<br />

therefore, sufficient rendering capacity exists, and in sufficiently dispersed locations,<br />

the capacity requirement might be eased.<br />

51.6 Non-waste Policies<br />

The waste sector is affected by a plethora <strong>of</strong> regulations and instruments which affect<br />

either all, or part <strong>of</strong>, a sector which is becoming increasingly heterogeneous. The<br />

move away from a ‘disposal oriented’ society necessarily moves ‘the waste sector’<br />

into a situation where, as the economy moves ‘waste’ materials into more valuable<br />

applications, the products and services so derived effectively compete in market<br />

sectors for these products and services. Hence, the waste sector is now intimately<br />

affected by policies and influences coming through from the commodity markets, and<br />

the energy / fuel markets.<br />

There is also a development in policy, and a parallel development in the economy,<br />

which also affects the physical size <strong>of</strong> the ‘waste sector’. This is the trend towards the<br />

prevention <strong>of</strong> waste at source, which is becoming uppermost in the minds <strong>of</strong><br />

businesses, as well as in the minds <strong>of</strong> policy makers. Moves to decouple waste<br />

generation from economic activity are likely to define a new era <strong>of</strong> waste and<br />

resources policy. Evidence <strong>of</strong> the deepening <strong>of</strong> these trends can be found in the latest<br />

version <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive, and in the increased significance being<br />

accorded, within OECD countries, to the theme <strong>of</strong> Sustainable Production and<br />

Consumption.<br />

In this sense, the ‘waste sector’ is in direct competition with the growing trends to:<br />

� dematerialise,<br />

� improve resource efficiency,<br />

� make use <strong>of</strong> ‘by-products’, and<br />

� to achieve bottom line gains / improvements in reputational utility through<br />

reducing waste generation.<br />

Underpinning both <strong>of</strong> these ‘increasing overlaps’ is the growing clamour to address<br />

the issue <strong>of</strong> climate change. Making deep cuts in emissions will not be possible in the<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> continuing improvement in the management <strong>of</strong> resources across the<br />

economy, and it seems likely to lead to increased pressure to:<br />

� reduce waste generation in the first place, and<br />

� increase the extent to which that waste which is generated is valorised, and in<br />

ways which contribute to reducing carbon emissions.


The growing strength <strong>of</strong> these interactions makes it increasingly challenging to<br />

understand ‘the drivers’ affecting the waste sector. This is for the simple reason that<br />

an increasingly broad array <strong>of</strong> policies and drivers is likely to exert influence on the<br />

waste sector as it continues to deepen the extent to which it ‘crosses over’ into<br />

productive sectors <strong>of</strong> the economy. This will be motivated increasingly strongly by<br />

growing concerns around climate change, these concerns themselves giving rise to<br />

new drivers and instruments, as well as changes in existing ones.<br />

51.6.1 Climate Change<br />

The National Climate Change Strategy was first introduced in October 2000 and<br />

detailed the proposed measures to be taken by Ireland to limit the emission <strong>of</strong><br />

greenhouse gases from all sectors <strong>of</strong> the economy. The Strategy was updated in April<br />

2007 by the Strategy for 2007-2012. 883<br />

The Strategy states that waste accounted for 2.5% <strong>of</strong> GHG emissions as reported<br />

under Ireland’s inventory in 2005. It is worth noting that under the Guidelines for<br />

National Greenhouse Gas Inventories, from the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate<br />

Change, the majority <strong>of</strong> GHGs from ‘the waste sector’ are associated with the<br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> the uncaptured portion <strong>of</strong> methane which is emitted from landfills.<br />

However, it should be noted that under the IPCC Guidelines, other emissions <strong>of</strong><br />

relevance to the waste sector are reported in different parts <strong>of</strong> the inventory. For<br />

example:<br />

721<br />

1. Biological treatment processes also lead to emissions <strong>of</strong> carbon dioxide,<br />

methane and nitrous oxide. The IPCC asks for these to be reported under the<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> sector;<br />

2. Where incinerators generate no useful energy, the emissions are reported<br />

under the <strong>Waste</strong> source category;<br />

3. Where incinerators do generate energy, their emissions are reported under the<br />

‘Energy’ sector emissions. Although all GHG emissions should be reported<br />

(including CO2 from non-fossil sources in waste), the emissions <strong>of</strong> greatest<br />

relevance are taken to be the CO2 emissions from fossil sources in waste, and<br />

the nitrous oxide emissions associated with combustion, as well as any<br />

methane resulting from incomplete combustion;<br />

4. Where stationary combustion <strong>of</strong> waste occurs in association with the<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> energy, these are reported under the relevant sector under the<br />

Energy sector. Similar considerations apply (in terms <strong>of</strong> the way GHGs are<br />

reported) as for incineration. Activities <strong>of</strong> relevance here are, for example, the<br />

co-incineration <strong>of</strong> solid recovered fuels or wood wastes in power stations etc.;<br />

5. The ‘Industrial Processes and Product Use’ (IPPU) part <strong>of</strong> IPCC Guidance<br />

covers industries such as the cement industry, and the production <strong>of</strong> most<br />

materials and products. These all are <strong>of</strong> relevance to the waste sector ins<strong>of</strong>ar<br />

as their emissions are affected by the degree to which they make use <strong>of</strong><br />

883 DoEHLG (2007) Ireland: National Climate Change Strategy, 2007-2012, April 2007.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


722<br />

29/09/09<br />

secondary materials. There is, as the authors <strong>of</strong> the IPPU Guidance note, some<br />

difficulty in allocating emissions to the IPPU or Energy Sectors: 884<br />

Allocating emissions from the use <strong>of</strong> fossil fuel between the Energy and<br />

IPPU Sectors can be complex. The feedstock and reductant uses <strong>of</strong><br />

fuels frequently produce gases that may be combusted to provide<br />

energy for the process. Equally part <strong>of</strong> the feedstock may be<br />

combusted directly for heat. This can lead to uncertainty and ambiguity<br />

in reporting.<br />

The above suggests that although the ‘<strong>Waste</strong> Sector’ is frequently seen as a relatively<br />

small contributor to GHG inventories, in part, this reflects the nature <strong>of</strong> the (somewhat<br />

complex) accounting process for reporting these inventories, and that the emissions<br />

which appear under the ‘waste’ heading are principally those from landfilling. It<br />

should also be noted that as the waste and energy / fuel sectors deepen the extent <strong>of</strong><br />

their integration, and as the number <strong>of</strong> more novel processes dealing with waste and<br />

materials continues to grow, so the approach to assigning waste-related emissions to<br />

one or other category is likely to become more, not less, complex.<br />

Finally, it has to be noted that national inventories are based very much on emissions<br />

associated with domestic activity. They do not, for example, attempt to account for<br />

the embodied energy in imported and exported raw materials, goods and services.<br />

From a waste perspective, this raises important questions as to whether the existing<br />

approach to reporting inventories can really motivate the most desirable response<br />

from ‘the waste sector’. This is particularly important in countries like Ireland where<br />

the bulk <strong>of</strong> primary materials are imported, and where the bulk <strong>of</strong> secondary<br />

materials are exported. From the national inventory perspective, therefore, recycling<br />

<strong>of</strong> dry recyclables might not generate much by way <strong>of</strong> benefits. From the global<br />

perspective, however, the effect has the potential to be <strong>of</strong> considerable significance<br />

(see Annex 63.0).<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> actions in the waste sector, the previous strategy planned to achieve<br />

significant emissions reductions through diversion <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste away from<br />

landfill, and the improvement in landfill gas capture and utilisation. This is consistent<br />

with the narrower view <strong>of</strong> emissions associated with the reported inventory only.<br />

The updated Strategy also discussed the issue <strong>of</strong> residual waste. It states:<br />

To maximise the recovery <strong>of</strong> useful materials and energy from residual waste,<br />

the National Strategy on Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> identifies thermal treatment<br />

with energy recovery as the preferred option in most <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Plans adopted by local authorities. The National Strategy on Biodegradable<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> also recognises, particularly in the shorter term prior to the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> adequate thermal treatment capacity, a potential role for<br />

mechanical biological treatment (MBT). MBT should be expected to contribute<br />

to national energy recovery policy. In the absence <strong>of</strong> energy recovery potential,<br />

884 IPCC (2006) 2006 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories, Volume 3: Industrial<br />

Processes and Product Use, http://www.ipcc-nggip.iges.or.jp/public/2006gl/vol3.html


It goes on:<br />

723<br />

fully stabilised waste may be sent to landfill where alternative and more<br />

suitable treatment solutions are not available.<br />

In accordance with the methodologies developed by the Intergovernmental<br />

Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), the CO2 emissions resulting from the<br />

combustion <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste are considered carbon neutral and are<br />

not counted for the purposes <strong>of</strong> Kyoto obligations. In addition, generation <strong>of</strong><br />

heat and electricity from waste in thermal treatment plants reduces the need<br />

to produce this energy from fossil fuels and will therefore displace CO2<br />

emissions from these sources. By exploiting an indigenous energy source,<br />

waste-to-energy plants make a contribution to national security <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

supply.<br />

In the current process <strong>of</strong> revising the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive<br />

(2006/12/EC), mechanisms are being considered which would encourage<br />

waste-to-energy plants to increase efficiency to a level comparable to<br />

conventional power plants, thereby allowing the energy content within waste<br />

to be transformed into electricity and heat for beneficial use in accordance<br />

with Best Available Techniques. The Government supports this approach, in<br />

the context <strong>of</strong> the waste hierarchy, which will minimise climate impacts<br />

through the sustainable management <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

Whilst broadly correct (incinerators do not generate electricity with an efficiency<br />

approaching that <strong>of</strong> modern power plants), the above paragraphs do not mention the<br />

fact that it rarely the case that waste combustion facilities deal only with waste that is<br />

biodegradable. To that extent, not all the energy generated at such facilities is ‘carbon<br />

neutral’, and the generation <strong>of</strong> energy is typically accompanied by emissions <strong>of</strong> fossilderived<br />

CO2 from components <strong>of</strong> waste which consist <strong>of</strong> such material (under IPCC<br />

reporting, these emissions would be reported under the Energy). Consequently,<br />

additional GHG emissions would have to be reported under the Irish inventory, but<br />

these do not appear to be acknowledged anywhere in the document.<br />

In this light, one can assess the two new measures outlined in the Strategy, which<br />

are:<br />

� Use <strong>of</strong> waste biomass in energy production; and<br />

� Support for waste-to-energy projects under REFIT scheme.<br />

These are fleshed out in the document:<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> biomass encompasses not only the biodegradable component <strong>of</strong><br />

municipal and industrial waste, but also the biodegradable fraction <strong>of</strong><br />

products and residues from agriculture, forestry and related industries. The<br />

recently published Bioenergy Action Plan sets out an integrated strategy for<br />

harnessing the energy potential <strong>of</strong> all bioenergy sources, including waste<br />

biomass, to make a contribution to renewable energy.<br />

To assist in the development <strong>of</strong> waste to energy projects, the Government is<br />

extending REFIT to allow support for the renewable portion <strong>of</strong> mixed<br />

renewable and nonrenewable generation. This will allow waste-to-energy<br />

projects to obtain support for the renewable portion <strong>of</strong> the generated<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


724<br />

29/09/09<br />

electricity. This type <strong>of</strong> hybrid support mechanism is fully consistent with the<br />

overall ‘hierarchy <strong>of</strong> waste’ treatment approach.<br />

Whilst these measures are well-intended, there is no guarantee that, other than<br />

through avoiding landfilling <strong>of</strong> untreated waste, there might not be a net contribution<br />

to Ireland’s inventory <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gas emissions. It is not clear whether the<br />

Strategy has actually appreciated this fact. 885<br />

51.6.2 Bioenergy Action Plan<br />

The Bioenergy Action Plan merely reiterates what is stated in the NBS. However, the<br />

Plan states:<br />

The Strategy seeks to maximise the recovery <strong>of</strong> useful materials and energy<br />

from residual waste and accordingly suggests thermal treatment with energy<br />

recovery as the preferred option followed by mechanical biological treatment<br />

with energy recovery and with mechanical biological treatment <strong>of</strong> fully<br />

stabilised residue to landfill as a last resort.<br />

To assist in the development <strong>of</strong> waste to energy projects, REFIT will be<br />

extended to allow support for the renewable portion <strong>of</strong> mixed renewable and<br />

non-renewable generation. This would allow, for example, a waste to energy<br />

project to obtain support for the renewable portion <strong>of</strong> the output. This type <strong>of</strong><br />

hybrid support mechanism is common in other EU Member States and is fully<br />

consistent with the overall ‘hierarchy <strong>of</strong> waste’ treatment approach.<br />

This is a slight misrepresentation <strong>of</strong> the position in the NBS, which does indeed list<br />

preferred options for dealing with residual waste, but it is not clear from the<br />

document that the ordering <strong>of</strong> this list necessarily represents an explicit order <strong>of</strong><br />

preference.<br />

51.6.3 REFIT<br />

The REFIT program was introduced in 2006 and guarantees power prices for all<br />

registered renewable power generators. Although originally intended for new-build<br />

plants, the programme is now being extended to existing plants to promote co-firing <strong>of</strong><br />

biomass. The goal is to attract sufficient confidence for investment finance and loan<br />

capital which may not otherwise be provided.<br />

The Irish government will fund the 15-yr guaranteed feed-in tariff in compliance with<br />

the EU Directive on Electricity Production from Renewable Sources, intending to<br />

generate 15% <strong>of</strong> electricity consumption from renewable sources by 2010, and 33%<br />

885 The RPS Characterisation study suggest that the contribution <strong>of</strong> plastics in residual household<br />

waste is <strong>of</strong> the order 13.6%. Combustion <strong>of</strong> this material would release approximately 360-400kg <strong>of</strong><br />

CO2. If the facility generates only electricity, then even if 650kWh electricity, net, is generated per<br />

tonne <strong>of</strong> waste (this is a high figure), then the CO2 displaced from CCGT sourced electricity will be <strong>of</strong><br />

the order 240-260kg CO2 equ. In other words, it is difficult to see how the conclusion could be reached<br />

that this would benefit Ireland’s position in terms <strong>of</strong> climate change.


<strong>of</strong> electricity consumption from renewable sources by 2020. 886 Tariffs for the<br />

schemes initially included ranged from 5.7 eurocents/KWh for large wind farm power<br />

to 7.2 eurocents/kWh for biomass energy (see Table 51-5), with these being indexed<br />

over time in line with changes in the consumer price index. By definition, biomass<br />

includes the biodegradable fraction <strong>of</strong> MSW. The energy white paper has already<br />

proposed extending REFIT to co-firing. 887 Wave energy was added to the list <strong>of</strong><br />

supported technologies in 2008. 888<br />

Table 51-5: REFIT Tariffs for Electricity Categories (2006 prices)<br />

Category Category Category<br />

Tariff Tariff Tariff (eur (eurocents (eur (eurocents<br />

ocents per per kWh) kWh)<br />

Large Scale Wind 5.7<br />

Small Scale Wind 5.9<br />

Hydro 7.2<br />

Biomass – Landfill Gas 7.0<br />

Other Biomass 7.2<br />

Wave 22.0<br />

Note: The above reference prices will be adjusted annually in line with the change in<br />

the consumer price index in Ireland commencing 1 January 2007.<br />

Discussions with Regulators suggest that where mixed residual waste is concerned,<br />

there is, as yet, no clear way <strong>of</strong> defining the contribution <strong>of</strong> biomass to the calorific<br />

content <strong>of</strong> the waste. Hence, it is not yet entirely clear how facilities treating mixed<br />

waste, whether as a whole, or an SRF derived from mixed waste, would be affected by<br />

the scheme. We understand that DCENR is liaising with the EPA on this matter.<br />

51.6.4 Summary Comment on Non-waste Policies<br />

There has always been an overlap between waste and energy policy. The pressing<br />

global issue <strong>of</strong> climate change, as well as geopolitical considerations <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

886 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Communications, Marine and Natural Resources (2007) Delivering a Sustainable<br />

Energy Future for Ireland: The Energy <strong>Policy</strong> Framework 2007-2020,<br />

http://www.dcmnr.gov.ie/NR/rdonlyres/54C78A1E-4E96-4E28-A77A-<br />

3226220DF2FC/27356/EnergyWhitePaper12March2007.pdf<br />

887 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Communications, Marine and Natural Resources (2007) Delivering a Sustainable<br />

Energy Future for Ireland: The Energy <strong>Policy</strong> Framework 2007-2020,<br />

http://www.dcmnr.gov.ie/NR/rdonlyres/54C78A1E-4E96-4E28-A77A-<br />

3226220DF2FC/27356/EnergyWhitePaper12March2007.pdf<br />

888 NDP Funded Ocean Energy Initiative Launched, 15 January 2008,<br />

http://www.ndp.ie/docs/NDP_Funded_Ocean_Energy_Initiative_Launched_-<br />

_15_January_200/2034.htm<br />

725<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


security, appear to be increasing the extent, and the significance <strong>of</strong> the overlap<br />

between policies.<br />

It is tempting for those responsible for policies on energy and climate change to<br />

assume that the best use <strong>of</strong> waste is to generate energy from it, and to generate as<br />

much as possible. This is not necessarily the case. Furthermore, where climate<br />

change is concerned, the measure <strong>of</strong> ‘best’ must also consider whether what matters<br />

from the perspective <strong>of</strong> policy are the emissions reported to the IPCC, or the impact <strong>of</strong><br />

the activity from the perspective <strong>of</strong> the global environment.<br />

In recent work in the UK for Defra, the Committee on Climate Change and the<br />

Environment Agency, Eunomia developed marginal abatement cost curves for<br />

greenhouse gas emissions from the waste sector. Decisions regarding the best<br />

management route were not greatly affected by the choice <strong>of</strong> perspective. However,<br />

this may be more coincidence than a robust outcome.<br />

It is worth pointing out that in the medium- to long-term, a globally integrated carbon<br />

market would make the distinction less relevant. In our analysis below (see Annex<br />

63.0), partly for this reason, and partly because we are interested in assessing the<br />

impacts <strong>of</strong> activities in the waste sector (as opposed to their impact on an inventory<br />

under particular accounting rules), we have assumed that what matter is the impact<br />

<strong>of</strong> the activity from the perspective <strong>of</strong> the global environment. This is consistent with<br />

general practice in respect <strong>of</strong> cost benefit analysis. 889<br />

889 It is worth noting, in passing, that the UK has recently issued new Guidance on public sector<br />

projects regarding climate change emissions. In the suggested approach, the social costs <strong>of</strong><br />

greenhouse gas emissions are assumed to be different depending upon whether the emissions are<br />

within the traded or non-traded (i.e. EU-ETS) sectors (with the two converging in 2030). So, for<br />

example, the benefits from generating electricity would be valued at the social cost related to the<br />

traded sector, whilst avoided transport emissions from the production <strong>of</strong> biomethane would be valued<br />

at the social cost for emissions outside the EU-ETS). Eunomia is currently applying this methodology in<br />

the context <strong>of</strong> a cost-benefit analysis for WRAP on the potential impact <strong>of</strong> landfill bans as applied to the<br />

UK.<br />

726<br />

29/09/09


52.0 Policies Aimed at Discouraging Disposal<br />

In this section the main policy mechanisms that have the primary aim <strong>of</strong> discouraging<br />

the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste are considered. The main policy instruments evaluated in this<br />

section are:<br />

727<br />

• waste taxes<br />

• bans on landfilling / incinerating specific waste types; and<br />

• tradable allowances schemes.<br />

We have chosen to look at these instruments in combination, viewed from a countryspecific<br />

(rather than instrument-specific) perspective. This is because the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

the individual policies have to be seen in the broader context <strong>of</strong> the suite <strong>of</strong><br />

instruments used to influence the quantity <strong>of</strong>, and treatment <strong>of</strong>, residual waste.<br />

There is an English saying which speaks about the desirability <strong>of</strong> ‘killing two birds with<br />

one stone’. Textbooks in economics have tended to be sceptical about the<br />

possibilities <strong>of</strong> realising the promises <strong>of</strong> this allegory in practical policy making ever<br />

since the publication <strong>of</strong> Jan Tinbergen’s book “On the Theory <strong>of</strong> Economic <strong>Policy</strong>” in<br />

1952. Tinbergen emphasised the need for having as many instruments as one has<br />

policy objectives. This is quite important in the context <strong>of</strong> how one approaches one’s<br />

understanding <strong>of</strong> the effectiveness <strong>of</strong>, for example, landfill bans, or landfill taxes, or<br />

allowances for landfilling. For example, the principle objective <strong>of</strong> a landfill ban is, to<br />

state the obvious, to ban the targeted materials from landfill. Similarly, the principle<br />

objective <strong>of</strong> a landfill tax is to increase the price <strong>of</strong> landfill compared with other<br />

alternative management methods.<br />

Neither a ban nor a tax can, in and <strong>of</strong> themselves, determine how the material which<br />

is no longer landfilled is managed. This will be determined, in general, by what we<br />

might call ‘the background policy environment’, which will affect the relative prices <strong>of</strong><br />

the alternative management options. This is important in what follows. Landfill taxes<br />

and bans do not, in and <strong>of</strong> themselves, lead directly to the promotion <strong>of</strong> recycling or<br />

waste prevention. They can, however, assist in meeting these objectives where the<br />

background policy environment is aligned with achieving these objectives.<br />

It is important to note that the options available to different actors who might appear<br />

to be targeted by these policy instruments are different depending upon who the<br />

actor is. A householder, for example, at least where most households are connected<br />

to the collection service (as in most countries other than Ireland) only has the choice<br />

to segregate into different waste streams, whereas a municipality has the choice <strong>of</strong><br />

altering collection systems available, and procuring treatment facilities for residual<br />

waste other than landfill. A commercial or industrial enterprise can, to some extent,<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


make both decisions. 890 Policies <strong>of</strong> this type do, therefore, affect different agents in<br />

different ways, hence increasing the complexity <strong>of</strong> any analysis.<br />

The review given here firstly outlines the policies, prior to summarising specifics<br />

within the individual countries, then describes the environmental benefits associated<br />

with a reduction in the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste disposed.<br />

A caveat around the definition <strong>of</strong> ‘municipal’ waste is important to note. Differing<br />

countries will include various waste streams in their national definitions making<br />

comparison difficult. This is true, more generally, for statistics concerning municipal<br />

waste derived by e.g. EUROSTAT and the European Environment Agency.<br />

52.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

52.1.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Taxes<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> taxes are applied to either landfill, or to both landfill and incineration. They are<br />

usually set on the basis <strong>of</strong> the weight <strong>of</strong> material sent to the facility, but some taxes,<br />

notably those for incineration, are now being designed with the intention <strong>of</strong><br />

addressing the level <strong>of</strong> air emissions in a direct manner.<br />

Of the two main types <strong>of</strong> tax applied, landfill taxes are the more widely used <strong>of</strong> the<br />

two. The main aim <strong>of</strong> these fiscal measures is to discourage the management <strong>of</strong><br />

residual waste through processes that generate significant levels <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

pollution, thereby promoting prevention and re-use, recycling, and alternative residual<br />

technologies. In addition they may be implemented to force landfill operators to<br />

upgrade technology and increase measures for pollution reduction.<br />

Economic instruments, such as taxes, are seen as appropriate tools for implementing<br />

the “polluter pays” principle, which has become the widely accepted framework for<br />

internalising environmental externalities. 891 However, relatively few countries have<br />

based their tax rates upon an estimate <strong>of</strong> the external costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling or<br />

incineration. Some exceptions are the UK landfill tax 892 , and the Norwegian tax on<br />

pollutants from incineration. 893<br />

Although market based instruments, such as taxes, are deemed to be more efficient<br />

as a mechanism for changing behaviour (because in theory, market based systems<br />

equalize the marginal level <strong>of</strong> pollution abatement costs among firms, and hence<br />

890 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005<br />

891 European Environment Agency (2005) Market-based instruments for environmental policy in<br />

Europe, EEA Technical report No 8/2005,<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/technical_report_2005_8/en/EEA_technical_report_8_2005.pdf<br />

892 See CSERGE, EFTEC and Warren Spring Laboratory (1993) Externalities from Landfill and<br />

Incineration, London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.<br />

893 See T H Martinsen and E Vassnes (2004) <strong>Waste</strong> Tax in Norway, in OECD (2004) Addressing the<br />

Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, Paris: OECD.<br />

728<br />

29/09/09


promote cost effective means <strong>of</strong> responding to the incentive), this does depend upon<br />

the level <strong>of</strong> the tax, and also, upon the extent to which other activities are treated in a<br />

similar manner. In this context, we note that whereas most disposal technologies<br />

have associated with them a net environmental cost, recycling tends to generate net<br />

external benefits. Consequently, taxes on landfill, and to a lesser degree, incineration,<br />

have been used pragmatically to promote recycling and other residual waste<br />

treatments rather than to ‘internalise externalities’.<br />

UK experience with the landfill tax has been interesting in this regard– initially set<br />

through reference to a study on the external costs <strong>of</strong> landfill and incineration, the tax<br />

has now departed significantly from the initial levels, and no subsequent study <strong>of</strong> an<br />

equivalent nature has been carried out to justify the change. On the contrary, the<br />

most recent study emerging from government actually suggested the external costs <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill were far lower than the tax rate which currently prevails, and lower than those<br />

for incineration, which is subject to no such tax. 894 Although the study was carried out<br />

in the context <strong>of</strong> a commitment to review the case for an incineration tax, no such tax<br />

exists in the UK.<br />

It is an interesting point that no country has considered all options for residual waste<br />

management with a view to treating them all on an equivalent basis. Some studies<br />

have been carried out which seek to propose alternative instrument designs for<br />

landfill and incineration taxes. 895 However, these tend to be limited to one or other <strong>of</strong><br />

the main disposal options (landfill and incineration). Relatively few studies have<br />

assessed the external costs <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment other than incineration and<br />

landfill (see also Annex 63.0). 896<br />

Responsibility for fiscal policy generally resides at the level <strong>of</strong> the nation state. Hence,<br />

taxes tend to be implemented on a national level. They can, however, be<br />

administered, and the revenues collected, at a regional level, where such<br />

competence resides with regions.<br />

52.1.2 Bans and Restrictions on Landfilling and Incineration<br />

All European countries are required to implement bans and restrictions on the<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive. This outlaws the<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong>:<br />

729<br />

• Whole and shredded tyres;<br />

• Liquid wastes;<br />

894 HM Customs & Excise (2004) Combining the Government’s two heath and environment studies to<br />

calculate estimates for the external costs <strong>of</strong> landfill and incineration, December 2004.<br />

895 See, for example, A. Bjorklund and G. Finnvenden (2007) Lifecycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> a National <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Proposal – the Case <strong>of</strong> a Swedish Incineration Tax, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, Vol.27, Issue 8, pp.1046-58.<br />

896 Exceptions are Eunomia and Tobin (2008) Meeting Ireland’s <strong>Waste</strong> Targets: The role <strong>of</strong> MBT – Final<br />

Report for Greenstar, Dublin, Ireland, and in respect <strong>of</strong> climate change impacts only, Eunomia (2008)<br />

Greenhouse Gas Balances <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Scenarios, Report for the Greater London Authority.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


730<br />

• <strong>Waste</strong>s which are explosive, corrosive, oxidising, flammable or infectious; and<br />

• <strong>Waste</strong>s which have not been pre-treated.<br />

Several countries have implemented bans which go beyond this, and seek to ensure<br />

either:<br />

1) That specific materials are not landfilled or incinerated;<br />

2) That specific types <strong>of</strong> material are not landfilled; or<br />

3) That only materials which meet specific criteria can be landfilled.<br />

We refer to the first two <strong>of</strong> the above as ‘bans’ the third as ‘restrictions’.<br />

The rationale for bans and restrictions is typically one, or sometimes both, <strong>of</strong> the<br />

following:<br />

1) To promote upstream changes in material use;<br />

2) To move waste management up the hierarchy;<br />

3) To ensure that the input materials to landfills, and to a lesser degree, incinerators,<br />

do not lead to situations where there is increased likelihood <strong>of</strong> emissions being<br />

problematic.<br />

Bans and restrictions are generally implemented with fairly significant lead-times. This<br />

reflects the view that if bans / restrictions are to be implemented, then alternative<br />

infrastructure must be developed to enable the banned / restricted materials to be<br />

managed in alternative ways.<br />

52.1.3 Allowances for Landfilling / Incineration<br />

The UK is, as far as we are aware, the only country which makes use <strong>of</strong> a system <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill allowances. The Landfill Allowance Schemes (LASs) operate differently in the<br />

four devolved administrations <strong>of</strong> England, Scotland and Wales. 897 The LASs were<br />

designed specifically in response to the Landfill Directive and were intended to deliver<br />

compliance with the Article 5 targets under the Landfill Directive at least cost to the<br />

UK. The rationale, therefore, is specifically to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> biodegradable<br />

waste being sent to landfill over time.<br />

Allowances are issued to all local authorities with responsibility for waste disposal<br />

(waste disposal authorities, or WDAs). In England, the allowances have been made<br />

tradable. Sanctions are to be applied in the event <strong>of</strong> non-compliance, these being set<br />

at punitive levels to deliver the required changes in management and infrastructure.<br />

Some discussion has taken place in Wales concerning the possibility <strong>of</strong> restricting<br />

incineration <strong>of</strong> municipal waste. The Welsh Assembly Government is in the process <strong>of</strong><br />

reviewing its waste strategy and is considering mechanisms to ensure that local<br />

authorities do not exceed a maximum proportion <strong>of</strong> energy from waste (though where<br />

897 At the time <strong>of</strong> writing (April 2009), the scheme has been suspended in Scotland.<br />

29/09/09


authorities work jointly on a strategy, it seems likely that they will be able to ‘trade’<br />

their obligations in respect <strong>of</strong> recycling and energy from waste).<br />

This instrument is discussed in more detail in Annex 55.0.<br />

52.2 Where Have the Policies Been Applied, and Why?<br />

52.2.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Taxes<br />

There are many waste taxes in place around the world, though mostly to be found in<br />

Europe. A number have been in place for many years, but many countries outside <strong>of</strong><br />

the EU have just implemented, or are about to implement, such policies. The only<br />

non-EU countries found to have had a policy in place for a number <strong>of</strong> years are<br />

Norway and Australia, with Norway being heavily influenced by EU policy<br />

developments.<br />

The basis for, and levels <strong>of</strong>, waste taxes vary from country to country. The basis for<br />

taxation is usually weight, and in the case <strong>of</strong> some incinerator taxes, levels <strong>of</strong><br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> specified pollutants.<br />

Where landfills are concerned, most taxes are set on a ‘per tonne’ basis. In Europe,<br />

landfill tax levels vary from €0 per tonne to around €85 per tonne. Some countries<br />

opt for a two tier structure whereby there is a differentiation between inert wastes,<br />

and active, or combustible, wastes, the latter being a net contributor to global<br />

methane emissions if left to degrade anaerobically in landfill.<br />

Incineration taxes range from €3 per tonne to €49 per tonne, though several taxes<br />

are not set with the tonnage as the tax base.<br />

In Europe, some <strong>of</strong> the policies mentioned in this section have been developed partly<br />

in response to the Landfill Directive, though several countries have taxes which predate<br />

the Directive. 898 In those countries with such policies in place for a longer period<br />

<strong>of</strong> time, motivations have included:<br />

731<br />

• diminishing landfill void space;<br />

• problems with old landfills (and the desire to generate revenues to address<br />

these);<br />

• internalisation <strong>of</strong> externalities;<br />

• incentivising a move, in the management <strong>of</strong> waste, up the hierarchy;<br />

• shifting relative prices between landfill and incineration (in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

incineration); and<br />

• arguably (though this is not <strong>of</strong>ten so baldly stated), as the taxes have bedded<br />

in, revenue raising for the Finance Ministry concerned.<br />

898 Directive 1999/31/EC on Landfill <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Common to these policies is a desire to discourage disposal <strong>of</strong> (untreated) waste to<br />

landfill.<br />

Not all countries with landfill taxes have chosen to implement incineration taxes.<br />

However, no country with an incineration tax in place does NOT also have a landfill<br />

tax, and this is set, in all countries, at a higher rate than for incineration.<br />

Notwithstanding this point, and reflecting the discussion above, it is by no means<br />

clear that such a treatment is justified on environmental grounds in an unequivocal<br />

manner, especially if what is landfilled is pre-treated to render it less problematic in<br />

the landfill. Following the increased attention on GHG emissions (due to climate<br />

change impacts), and recognising that the emissions from incinerators can vary in<br />

line with input materials and with the nature <strong>of</strong> flue gas treatment used, incineration<br />

taxes are now emerging which seek to directly address these externalities.<br />

52.2.2 Regulations and Bans<br />

Many countries also operate bans and restrictions. Typical targets for landfill bans<br />

are:<br />

732<br />

• Source segregated materials;<br />

• Biodegradable wastes;<br />

• Combustible wastes<br />

• Household waste; and<br />

• Municipal waste.<br />

Most restrictions <strong>of</strong> interest to this study (excluding those <strong>of</strong> a more technical nature)<br />

relate to the biodegradability <strong>of</strong> waste sent to landfill, sometimes allied to a restriction<br />

on the calorific value <strong>of</strong> waste that may be landfilled. These are in place in Austria,<br />

Germany, Finland and Italy, whilst the UK includes measures to assess the<br />

biodegradability <strong>of</strong> waste under the LASs (see below).<br />

52.2.3 Landfill Allowances<br />

The only landfill allowances schemes are those <strong>of</strong> the devolved administrations <strong>of</strong> the<br />

UK. These apply to biodegradable municipal waste, with the quantity allowed to be<br />

sent to landfill restricted in line with allowances issued to WDAs. The biodegradability<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste landfilled is assessed through an accounting mechanism which is based<br />

around an estimate <strong>of</strong> the biodegradability <strong>of</strong> municipal waste, and the<br />

biodegradability <strong>of</strong> specific components <strong>of</strong> waste which are dealt with through<br />

recycling and composting.<br />

52.2.4 Country Specific Characteristics: Summary<br />

The policies in place vary from country to country. Table 52-1 highlights which policies<br />

are in place in which country.<br />

Note that the rates for commercial and industrial wastes are the same as for MSW in<br />

most countries.<br />

29/09/09


Table 52-1: Summary <strong>of</strong> Measures by <strong>Policy</strong> Approach (MSW)<br />

Country Country<br />

Landfill Landfill Tax Tax<br />

Incineration Incineration Incineration Tax Tax<br />

Landfill Landfill Ban<br />

Ban<br />

Year Year Year <strong>of</strong><br />

Tax Tax Rate Rate (MSW,<br />

(MSW, Date Date <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> Tax Tax Rate Rate Rate (MSW,<br />

(MSW, (Date (Date <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Announcement)<br />

Announcement)<br />

Implementation<br />

Implementation<br />

Implementation €/tonne)<br />

€/tonne) Impleme Implementation<br />

Impleme Impleme ntation<br />

€/tonne<br />

€/tonne Date Date <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Implementation<br />

Implementation<br />

South Australia 1993 10.8<br />

Western Australia 1998 3.4<br />

New Zealand 2008 4.3 ($10) 899<br />

Austria 1989 87/26 900 1996 7 2004<br />

Finland 1996 30 2005 901<br />

Germany 2001<br />

Hungary 2000<br />

Italy 1996 26902 2003/<br />

2007<br />

Belgium-Flanders 1987 60 7 2005<br />

899 Calculated using an exchange rate <strong>of</strong> 0.430524 on 24/04/2009.<br />

733<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Scope Scope <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Ban<br />

Ban<br />

Biodegradability and<br />

other criteria<br />

Biodegradable and<br />

compostable waste<br />

Biodegradability and<br />

other criteria<br />

Biodegradability and<br />

other criteria<br />

Unsorted wastes<br />

Sorted and non-sorted<br />

wastes for recovery<br />

Combustible residual<br />

fraction from sorting<br />

900 The €87 per tonne figure was applied for untreated MSW and is now more or less moribund. The €26 per tonne is for material which has undergone<br />

mechanical biological treatment. For MSW to be treated thermally the tax is €7 per tonne which results in a broadly equal position between MBT and<br />

incineration when one considers that the tax applies to the landfilled output from the MBT process, not the input. If 25 – 30 % <strong>of</strong> the plant input is landfilled,<br />

then the tax on MBT broadly equates to that on incineration.<br />

901 This ban is in revision at present<br />

902 Highest rate is given. Lowest rate set regionally can be €10.


Country Country<br />

Landfill Landfill Tax Tax<br />

Incineration Incineration Tax Tax<br />

Landfill Landfill Ban<br />

Ban<br />

Year Year Year <strong>of</strong><br />

Implementation<br />

Implementation<br />

Implementation<br />

Tax Tax Rate Rate (MSW, (MSW,<br />

(MSW,<br />

€/tonne)<br />

€/tonne)<br />

Date Date <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

Impleme Implementation<br />

Impleme Impleme ntation<br />

Tax Tax Rate Rate Rate (MSW,<br />

(MSW,<br />

€/tonne<br />

€/tonne<br />

(Date (Date (Date <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Announcement)<br />

Announcement)<br />

Date Date <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Implementation<br />

Implementation<br />

Implementation<br />

Scope Scope <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Ban<br />

Ban<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>s suitable for<br />

incineration<br />

Belgium-Wallonia 3 2004 Various<br />

Denmark 1987 50 1993 44 1997 Combustible waste<br />

France 1992 9.15 2002 ‘Ultimate <strong>Waste</strong> Flows’<br />

The Netherlands 1996 85 1996<br />

Various, incl<br />

household waste<br />

Norway 1999 40 Pollutant based From mid-2009 Biodegradable waste<br />

Sweden 2000 43 2006 49<br />

2002<br />

2006<br />

Combustible waste<br />

Organic waste<br />

Czech Republic 1991 16 1997: Paper, 2004: BMW<br />

Estonia 1990 8 2008<br />

Slovakia 1992 7.9<br />

Slovenia 2001 2001<br />

Spain – Catalonia 2003 10 2008 5 None<br />

United Kingdom 1996 45<br />

Under consideration by<br />

devolved administrations<br />

Source: Eunomia<br />

734<br />

29/09/09


It is illuminating to note that in all those countries which the EEA categorises as<br />

having ‘high incineration rates’ that incineration is subject to a tax. However, as the<br />

Table also indicates, in all cases, taxes on landfill are higher and /or bans on<br />

landfilling certain materials are in place. It is also interesting to note that in many<br />

nations with landfill bans in place, landfill taxes are also in place, and are at high<br />

levels. The UK has argued against the deployment <strong>of</strong> an incineration tax on the basis<br />

that incineration is likely to be required to meet landfill directive targets. This position<br />

seems not to adequately appreciate that a tax on incineration is entirely consistent<br />

with the deployment <strong>of</strong> incineration, with incineration made more likely where the<br />

policy instruments affecting landfilling (e.g. differential tax rates, or the deployment <strong>of</strong><br />

bans on landfilling) tip the economic and regulatory balance firmly in favour <strong>of</strong><br />

incineration.<br />

Figure 52-1 shows the level <strong>of</strong> taxes for landfilling <strong>of</strong> non-inert materials in Europe (as<br />

well as increases already planned).<br />

Figure 52-1: Current and Planned Increases in Non-Inert Landfill Taxation in Europe<br />

Landfill Tax (€ per tonne)<br />

735<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Netherlands<br />

Belgium (Fl)<br />

Denmark<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

UK<br />

Sweden<br />

Norway<br />

Belgium (Wal)<br />

Finland<br />

Austria<br />

Country<br />

Italy<br />

Ireland<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Landfill Tax (Euro/tonne) Planned increases<br />

Source: Table 52-1: Summary <strong>of</strong> Measures by <strong>Policy</strong> Approach<br />

Spain - Catalonia<br />

A brief summary <strong>of</strong> the policy mechanisms will be described in the same order<br />

presented in Table 52-1. This is to so that interesting factors can be easily drawn out<br />

and used to weigh up the different instruments in use. Detailed descriptions for all<br />

the countries concerned follow this in Sections 52.2.4.1 to 52.2.4.20.<br />

� Australia: Both Southern and Western Australia have landfill taxes in place.<br />

Southern Australia levies the tax depending on whether the waste is<br />

Swiss<br />

France<br />

Estonia<br />

Slovakia


736<br />

29/09/09<br />

cosmopolitan 903 or not, and Western Australia has rates for putrescible waste<br />

per tonne, and inert waste by volume (in m 3);<br />

� Austria: A differential waste tax was initially implemented with the aim <strong>of</strong><br />

encouraging an improvement in the level <strong>of</strong> technology used at landfills in<br />

order to reduce pollution. Following this, a landfill ban on waste with Total<br />

Organic Content (TOC) above 5% was introduced. <strong>Waste</strong> which fails to meet<br />

this criterion has to be either incinerated, or treated in mechanical biological<br />

treatment (MBT) facilities. Where the waste is treated in MBT facilities, the<br />

resultant residue – which has to meet a specified threshold for biological<br />

stability - is subjected to a landfill disposal tax <strong>of</strong> around one quarter <strong>of</strong> that<br />

untreated waste.<br />

� Finland: A landfill tax was introduced against the backdrop <strong>of</strong> low waste<br />

management costs. The aim was to stimulate waste minimisation and material<br />

reuse, and to reduce landfilling. Furthermore a ban on landfilling was<br />

introduced in 2005 to reduce landfilling <strong>of</strong> BMW and to divert any other<br />

materials that could cause environmental damage in the long term through<br />

being landfilled. Two routes can be adopted to comply with the BMW ban:<br />

firstly, by introducing separate food waste collections; secondly, through<br />

stabilising the waste through MBT prior to landfilling.<br />

� Germany: A comprehensive landfill ban was introduced as large quantities <strong>of</strong><br />

waste were being landfilled due to its relatively cheap cost. It includes<br />

untreated household waste, and wastes with total organic carbon content<br />

>5%. The ban was known about for 12 years prior to its implementation,<br />

allowing for approaches to adapt in order to manage the regulation.<br />

� Hungary: A landfill ban was introduced in 2000. It covers several material<br />

steams such as hazardous and organic waste. The ban on organic waste has<br />

been staggered over time to 2016, most likely to allow for collection systems<br />

and infrastructure to develop.<br />

� Italy: A waste tax to promote materials and energy recovery was followed by<br />

landfill bans to reduce hazardous materials deposited in landfills. The tax rate<br />

can be set regionally within National limits and the revenue is used to fund<br />

environmental programmes and regional protection agencies.<br />

� Belgium - Flanders: The system in Flanders is the most complex out <strong>of</strong> all the<br />

policies evaluated in this report, but also one <strong>of</strong> the most effective. Landfill<br />

bans are in place for; unsorted household waste; waste collected for the<br />

purpose <strong>of</strong> recovery or that which is fit for recycling; and incinerable residues<br />

from sorting processes. In addition incineration bans are in effect for unsorted<br />

waste and waste fit for material recovery or recycling, except some types <strong>of</strong><br />

biowaste that have a calorific value above 11.5 MJ/kg and is used for the<br />

creation <strong>of</strong> renewable energy. The Flemish landfill and incineration tax regime<br />

includes 37 different regimes and tariffs. In essence, these have been<br />

903 ‘Cosmopolitan’ waste is broadly similar to municipal waste.


737<br />

implemented to make treatment options that are more environmentally<br />

damaging more expensive.<br />

� Denmark: There has been a general waste tax operating in Denmark for over 2<br />

decades now. It is differentiated so that landfilling is expensive, incineration is<br />

less expensive and recycling is untaxed. Since the implementation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

waste tax, a ban on landfilling combustible waste has also been introduced.<br />

The overall aim is to promote the use <strong>of</strong> waste as a source <strong>of</strong> energy for the<br />

extensive public owned district heating systems.<br />

� France: There is a general pollutants tax in force in France that includes<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste. Less tax is payable at landfills with environmental<br />

certifications, and more is payable at unlicensed sites. A landfill ban was<br />

introduced due to the slow effect <strong>of</strong> the tax policy, and covers several<br />

hazardous waste streams, and all biodegradable waste.<br />

� The Netherlands: Landfill bans and a tax were implemented concurrently with<br />

the aim to reduce waste sent to landfill and support capacity <strong>of</strong> the State’s<br />

incinerators. The instruments are specifically designed to target combustible<br />

waste so that as little as possible is landfilled.<br />

� Norway: A waste disposal tax was introduced in Norway to reduce methane<br />

emissions from landfill and incentivise the recovery <strong>of</strong> energy produced during<br />

incineration. Environmental objectives are supported by incentivising methane<br />

gas capture at landfills and increasing pollution control technology on<br />

incinerators through a pollutant based taxation system.<br />

� Sweden: There have been a range <strong>of</strong> policies applied in Sweden over time. The<br />

first was a landfill tax to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> material landfilled. Following<br />

this, a ban on landfilling combustible wastes was introduced to reduce<br />

environmental burdens and promote resource efficiency. A few years later a<br />

landfill ban on compostable waste was introduced, but exemptions are in<br />

place for waste with a Total Organic Content (TOC) <strong>of</strong> less than 10%. The<br />

Swedish energy policy heavily incentivises the use <strong>of</strong> waste as a source <strong>of</strong><br />

energy for district heating systems. Most plants were operating in a heat only<br />

mode, so in 2006 an incineration tax with differentiable rates was introduced<br />

to give plants generating electricity as well a competitive advantage, but also<br />

overall to further promote materials recycling and MBT treatments.<br />

� Czech Republic: All waste landfilled is subject to a basic rate <strong>of</strong> tax and there is<br />

a higher rate for any hazardous waste. There are also bans on the landfilling <strong>of</strong><br />

paper and all BMW.<br />

� Estonia: There is a tax levied on all waste landfilled. This is expected to rise<br />

sharply over the next few years. A ban on unsorted municipal waste is also<br />

expected from 2008.<br />

� Slovakia: There is a slightly different landfill taxation system in place in<br />

Slovakia which would incentivise municipalities to implement separate<br />

collections systems for recyclables. The level <strong>of</strong> taxation decreases<br />

incrementally as up to 5 separate waste streams are separately collected in<br />

the relevant area. So a municipality that separately collects 5 components will<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


738<br />

29/09/09<br />

pay less landfill tax on the residual stream than one that separately collects<br />

only 1 component.<br />

� Slovenia: A landfill tax is in place to raise revenue for technical improvement <strong>of</strong><br />

landfills, improvements in infrastructure and environmental remediation. A<br />

landfill ban has been implemented to restrict hazardous waste from certain<br />

categories <strong>of</strong> landfill, and to limit the deposition <strong>of</strong> BMW.<br />

� Spain (Catalonia): There is a landfill and incineration tax in this region <strong>of</strong> Spain.<br />

Its structure means that areas with separate biowaste collections have a<br />

reduced landfill or incineration tax. The revenue is to be used directly to<br />

improve collection and treatment infrastructure or for awareness raising<br />

campaigns.<br />

� United Kingdom: The main policy in place is a landfill tax. It is differentiated<br />

between inert and non-inert wastes, and for the previous 9 years has been<br />

increased though an escalator whereby increases are announced in the<br />

budget to take effect over future years. Some <strong>of</strong> the revenue is used to fund<br />

environmental projects and programmes relating to waste management. The<br />

UK has also introduced the Landfill Allowance Schemes for the devolved<br />

administrations. This is described further in Section 55.0.<br />

Data for this review has principally been gathered from European based studies, as<br />

there are many policies implemented in the EU. Landfill levies are in place in many<br />

areas <strong>of</strong> Australia. However, we have focused on the States <strong>of</strong> South and Western<br />

Australia as they have both produced evaluation studies, thus some <strong>of</strong> their effects<br />

can be analysed.<br />

52.2.4.1 South Australia<br />

Zero <strong>Waste</strong> SA was established on July 1, 2003 with the primary objectives <strong>of</strong><br />

promoting waste management practices that, as far as possible, eliminate waste or<br />

its consignment to landfill, advance the development <strong>of</strong> resource recovery and<br />

recycling, and are based on an integrated strategy for the State. 904 The function <strong>of</strong><br />

Zero <strong>Waste</strong> SA is, amongst other things to, from time to time, advise the Minister<br />

about the amount to be charged by way <strong>of</strong> the levy under Section 113 <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Environment Protection Act 1993.<br />

The use <strong>of</strong> landfill levies is the most prominent economic instrument being used in<br />

Australia to influence waste management behaviour. The levy in South Australia<br />

remained fairly static at around $4-5 per tonne until 2003, since when, it has seen<br />

incremental increases to $23.40 for metropolitan waste and $11.70 for nonmetropolitan<br />

waste. 50% <strong>of</strong> the revenue is paid into the <strong>Waste</strong> to Resources Fund<br />

pursuant to the Zero <strong>Waste</strong> SA Act. Of the remaining 50%, 5% goes to Environment<br />

Protection Fund as outlined in the Environment Protection Act to fund specific<br />

904 Hyder Consulting (2007) <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Solid <strong>Waste</strong> Levy, Report for Zero <strong>Waste</strong> SA,<br />

http://www.zerowaste.sa.gov.au/waste_levy_review.php


environmental projects, and 45% is paid into EPA recurrent funding for operations<br />

and environmental programs.<br />

Objectives for the use <strong>of</strong> landfill levies internationally and in Australia have variously<br />

comprised:<br />

739<br />

� Revenue generation;<br />

� Reduction in downstream environmental impacts associated with waste<br />

disposal; and<br />

� Promoting volumetric recycling and disposal targets, as a surrogate for<br />

reducing upstream environmental impacts associated with resource<br />

exploitation and material processing.<br />

Decisions in relation to the amount <strong>of</strong> the landfill levy and how it should be applied<br />

rest with the South Australian State Government.<br />

Recent studies suggest that 65% <strong>of</strong> waste material is being recycled or put to better<br />

use rather than being disposed <strong>of</strong> to landfill. However, and despite the many<br />

initiatives aimed at increasing sustainable resource recovery in South Australia,<br />

significant parts <strong>of</strong> the overall waste stream continue to be landfilled, with about 1<br />

million tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste going to landfill each year.<br />

52.2.4.2 Western Australia<br />

The Landfill Levy was introduced by the Western Australia State Government in 1998<br />

following an amendment to the Environmental Protection Act 1986. 905 A particular<br />

feature <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Levy is that the funds generated by the imposition <strong>of</strong> the levy<br />

are hypothecated, or earmarked, for strategic programs in the areas <strong>of</strong> management,<br />

reduction, reuse, recycling, monitoring or measurement <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

The levy revenues are credited to the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Recycling Account and<br />

the funds are disbursed in accordance with approval <strong>of</strong> the Minister for the<br />

Environment and Conservation on advice from the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board <strong>of</strong><br />

Western Australia.<br />

The levy has two functions:<br />

� to increase the comparative price for landfill and to make recycling more cost<br />

competitive; and<br />

� to provide resources for the state government to strategically invest in<br />

recycling initiatives.<br />

The Landfill Levy is an important policy instrument for achieving the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Board’s vision <strong>of</strong> towards zero waste, as outlined in the policy<br />

document Towards Zero <strong>Waste</strong> in Western Australia.<br />

905 Four Scenes (2007) Landfill Levy <strong>Review</strong>, Prepared for the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Boards <strong>of</strong> Western<br />

Australia.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


In 2006 the Government <strong>of</strong> Western Australia implemented a decision to<br />

progressively increase the landfill levy from AUS $3 per tonne to AUS $9 per tonne for<br />

putrescible waste and from AUS $1 per cubic meter to AUS $9 a cubic metre for inert<br />

waste to by 2010-11. The first increase occurred in October 2006, with unit increases<br />

<strong>of</strong> $1 for putrescible, and $2 for inert each year from 2008-09.<br />

52.2.4.3 Austria<br />

The Austrian <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act 2002 includes the basis for both federal and<br />

provincial waste management plans. The policies that are <strong>of</strong> significance in the<br />

current context are:<br />

740<br />

� The waste disposal fee for inter alia landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste, first implemented in<br />

1989; and<br />

� The ban on untreated waste going to landfills: <strong>Waste</strong> with Total Organic<br />

Content (TOC) above 5% has to be either incinerated or treated in mechanical<br />

biological facilities from 2004.<br />

The Austrian landfill tax (‘Altlastensanierungsbeitrag’, or AlsaG for short which refers<br />

to the respective legal matter Al Altlastensa Al<br />

sa sanierungsgesetz sa<br />

- Clean-Up <strong>of</strong> Contaminated<br />

Sites Act) was introduced to incentivise landfill operators to upgrade the level <strong>of</strong><br />

pollution control in place, improve greenhouse gas abatement and clean up<br />

contamination at their sites, with the revenue generated used for investment in waste<br />

management and to reduce waste disposed <strong>of</strong> at landfills.<br />

The legal basis for the policy was the 1989 Clean-Up <strong>of</strong> Contaminated Sites Act that<br />

was introduced following the emergence <strong>of</strong> environmental problems such as those at<br />

the ‘Fischer Deponie’, a waste disposal site where hazardous chemicals had been<br />

dumped, and which threatened the drinking water resources <strong>of</strong> some 500,000<br />

inhabitants. 906 The proponents <strong>of</strong> the Act foresaw increased work in surveying and<br />

identification <strong>of</strong> potentially problematic sites (<strong>of</strong>ten, old landfills), and the need to<br />

generate funding to contain and treat any potential or emerging problems.<br />

The tax was introduced in 1989 and since 1996 its rates have been differentiated<br />

according to the technical quality <strong>of</strong> the landfill site and to the type <strong>of</strong> waste. 907 In its<br />

most recent form, the tax is applied at a much lower rate where the waste has been<br />

subject to mechanical biological treatment (€26 per tonne) and meets specified<br />

criteria for landfilling, whereas for waste which has not been pre-treated, it is € 87 per<br />

tonne (this is more or less redundant today). There are also further surcharges <strong>of</strong> €29<br />

per tonne for cases where i) the landfill has no basement seal system or no vertical<br />

906 Umweltbundesamt (2000), <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> contaminated sites in Western Europe, Report for the<br />

European Environment Agency.<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/Topic_report_No_131999/en/topic_13_1999.pdf .<br />

907 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.<br />

29/09/09


enclosure; and ii) municipal waste landfills are operated without a landfill gas<br />

collection and treatment system. 908<br />

The legislation clearly states that the aim <strong>of</strong> the waste tax is to finance the<br />

containment and treatment <strong>of</strong> contaminated sites. Austria is the only European<br />

country where revenues from a landfill tax are exclusively used for this purpose. 909<br />

The activities supported include:<br />

741<br />

� The identification <strong>of</strong> problem sites;<br />

� The administration <strong>of</strong> those sites;<br />

� The direct containment and clean-up <strong>of</strong> sites;<br />

� The construction, or upgrading, <strong>of</strong> waste treatment plants at landfill sites; and<br />

� The development <strong>of</strong> new technologies for containment or treatment.<br />

It is the owner or operator <strong>of</strong> the landfill site who is responsible for paying the tax, or<br />

anyone carrying out structural work.<br />

The Ordinance on Landfilling was introduced in 1996. This legislation was introduced<br />

with the intention <strong>of</strong> banning certain materials from landfilling and included wastes<br />

such as:<br />

� Sludgy, pasty and fine-grained waste;<br />

� Liquid waste (except leachate);<br />

� High inflammable and explosive waste;<br />

� Gasses under pressure;<br />

� Substances leaching heavily on contact with water;<br />

� Infectious waste from hospitals or similar medical; and<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> for which the content <strong>of</strong> hazardous substances exceeds certain limit<br />

values.<br />

In addition, the Ordinance set a limit on waste which could be landfilled that stated<br />

that a ban applied to any waste with a carbon content in excess <strong>of</strong> 5%. This would<br />

have implied an effective ban on all residual waste. However, an exemption was<br />

explicitly designed for waste ‘originating from mechanical-biological pre-treatment,<br />

that is disposed in separated areas within a mass waste landfill site, if the upper<br />

calorific value gained by combustion <strong>of</strong> the dry matter is below 6000 kJ/kg. The<br />

mixing <strong>of</strong> waste originating from mechanical-biological pre-treatment with materials<br />

908 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Austrian <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Austria<br />

909 Umweltbundesamt (2000) Deponieabgaben im europäischen Vergleich, Federal Environment<br />

Agency - Austria, Vienna.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


or waste <strong>of</strong> low calorific value in order not to exceed the limit value, is not<br />

admissible.’<br />

In order to determine criteria for an environmentally sound process design and the<br />

suitability <strong>of</strong> MBT material in accordance with the requirements <strong>of</strong> the Austrian<br />

Landfill Ordinance, a Guideline for the Mechanical Biological Treatment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> 910<br />

was elaborated by a working group chaired by the Ministry for Agriculture and<br />

Forestry, Environment and Water <strong>Management</strong>. For obvious reasons, the focal points<br />

for this guideline are different to those for compost. In particular, attention is given to<br />

the characteristics which represent a desirable treatment from the point <strong>of</strong> view <strong>of</strong><br />

the end-point – the landfill – in particular, the respirometric. Equally, as made clear in<br />

a report for the Umweltbundesamt, the lower limit on calorific value has the effect<br />

that the biodegradable fraction <strong>of</strong> waste is split from higher calorific fractions which<br />

are generally being used for thermal recovery. 911<br />

The Ordinance, therefore, allows for the landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste where a fermentability<br />

threshold was not exceeded (replacing the limit on carbon content). The limit value<br />

suggested that the static respirometric index, measured using the AT4 methodology<br />

(giving the cumulative biological activity over 96 hours), should be less than<br />

7 mg O2 / g dm for all landfilled waste. The rationale behind this restriction was to<br />

‘reduce reactions in the landfill body and respective production <strong>of</strong> landfill gas and<br />

leachate’. 912 Either the carbon content <strong>of</strong> the waste, or its respirometric activity, could<br />

be reduced by incineration or mechanical biological treatment facilities in order to<br />

satisfy the conditions <strong>of</strong> the Ordinance.<br />

An incineration tax is also applied in Austria. The level <strong>of</strong> the tax is set at €7 per<br />

tonne. Because the Austrian Guidelines effectively require a splitting <strong>of</strong> the<br />

biodegradable and non-biodegradable fractions, the quantity <strong>of</strong> material being<br />

landfilled from an MBT process might be expected to be <strong>of</strong> the order 25-30% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

input. A tax at €26 per tonne on 0.3 tonnes <strong>of</strong> stabilised waste landfilled is equivalent<br />

to a tax on MBT <strong>of</strong> €6.50 to €8.66 per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste input to the MBT plant. This is<br />

more or less equivalent to the €7 per tonne figure applied for incineration.<br />

The Austrian system has been very effective in setting out what it aimed to do and<br />

has evolved to appreciate the environmental externalities associated with landfilling<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste with and without pre-treatment.<br />

910 Federal Ministry for Agriculture and Forestry, Environment and Water <strong>Management</strong> (2001)<br />

‘Guideline for the mechanical-biological treatment <strong>of</strong> waste’, delivered for notification to the European<br />

Commission, 12 October 2001.<br />

911 Lahl, Uwe, Barbara Zeschmar-Lahl and Thomas Angerer (2000) Entwicklungspotentiale der<br />

Mechanisch-biologischem Abfällbehandlung, Monograph M-125, Wien, June 2000.<br />

912 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Austrian <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Austria<br />

742<br />

29/09/09


52.2.4.4 Finland<br />

In 1993, two years before Finland joined the EU, the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act <strong>of</strong> 1978<br />

was updated and split into two complementary pieces <strong>of</strong> legislation, the <strong>Waste</strong> Act<br />

and the <strong>Waste</strong> Decree. 913 A year later, the <strong>Waste</strong> Tax Act was implemented requiring<br />

that tax was to be paid on waste deposited at landfills. The tax, on the landfill <strong>of</strong><br />

waste, was implemented in 1996 to stimulate waste minimisation and material<br />

reuse, and to reduce landfilling.<br />

Since January 2005, the tax rate has been € 30 per tonne. The tax was introduced<br />

against a background <strong>of</strong> a low cost <strong>of</strong> waste management, so that the increases had<br />

a significant impact on the cost <strong>of</strong> disposal. 914<br />

A landfill ban was introduced following the 2006 amendment (202/2006) to the<br />

Government Decision on Landfills (861/1997). This amended Decision set general<br />

restrictions on the depositing <strong>of</strong> wastes in landfill. Since that time, in addition to those<br />

wastes banned under the Landfill Directive, household waste, or similar, where the<br />

biodegradable fraction has not been separately collected may not be deposited in a<br />

landfill. The pre-treatment requirement effectively requires the waste to be stabilized<br />

before landfilling. The instrument does, therefore, afford the municipalities some<br />

flexibility giving them the choice to decide whether separate collections or new<br />

treatment infrastructure are most viable, but with the same aim <strong>of</strong> reducing the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> BMW landfilled.<br />

Anecdotal evidence from waste <strong>of</strong>ficers in Finland suggest that the ‘ban’ in current<br />

form is, however, ineffective an unenforceable. An EEA report notes: 915<br />

743<br />

The government enacted a landfill ban for certain waste streams partly as a<br />

result <strong>of</strong> the EU's debate on the Landfill Directive. The ban prohibits landfilling<br />

biodegradable waste 'from which the major part <strong>of</strong> the biodegradable waste<br />

has not been collected separately'. The wording is rather vague and does not<br />

refer to the aim <strong>of</strong> removing a minimum <strong>of</strong> 80 % organic matter before waste<br />

is landfilled, which features in the country's <strong>Waste</strong> Plan 2002. As a result, it<br />

leaves room for interpretation <strong>of</strong> what 'the major part' is. Although, the 2002<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Plan provided that more detailed restrictions for the landfill <strong>of</strong><br />

biodegradable waste would be passed in 2003, this was not implemented till<br />

2006.<br />

Consequently Finland is redesigning a stricter ban to be implemented in the near<br />

future. The most recent National <strong>Waste</strong> Plan states: 916<br />

913 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Finland <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Finland<br />

914 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.<br />

915 EEA (2009) Diverting <strong>Waste</strong> from Landfill: Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Policies in the<br />

European Union, EEA Report No 7.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


744<br />

29/09/09<br />

4.1.1 4.1.1 4.1.1 The The The legislative legislative legislative instruments instruments instruments used used used in in other other countries countries<br />

for restricting the<br />

disposal <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste at landfills (for example, a ban on placing<br />

biodegradable and combustible waste at landfills) will be examined. At the<br />

same time, urgent changes to the Government decision on landfills will be<br />

prepared so that the restrictions concerning the disposal <strong>of</strong> biodegradable<br />

waste at landfills can be put on a concrete basis, which would make the<br />

practical application <strong>of</strong> the restriction more efficient. Guidelines will be drawn<br />

up on how to determine the proportion <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste <strong>of</strong> the total<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> landfilled waste.<br />

No further details are available at this time.<br />

52.2.4.5 Germany<br />

See Annex 53.0 below.<br />

52.2.4.6 Hungary<br />

Hungary has a range <strong>of</strong> legislation to support its national waste management plan. 917<br />

Of relevance for this section is a ban on landfilling that was introduced in 2000. The<br />

ban includes all materials restricted under the EU Landfill Directive.<br />

Since 2003, the EEA reports landfilling <strong>of</strong> organic wastes has been partially banned,<br />

and that the amount permitted is gradually reducing in line with the interim targets for<br />

BMW. 918 It is not clear that this is indeed a genuine ban.<br />

52.2.4.7 Italy<br />

The Italian Environment Act covers the waste sector, along with many other<br />

environmental sectors. 919<br />

The two relevant policy instruments here are:<br />

� Tax on waste disposal introduced in 1996. This includes landfilling and<br />

incineration without energy recovery; and<br />

� A ban on landfilling introduced that is to progressively cover 12 material<br />

streams.<br />

916 Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment (Finland) (2009) Towards a Recycling Society: The National <strong>Waste</strong> Plan<br />

for 2016, Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Helsinki, Finland, April 2009,<br />

http://www.environment.fi/download.asp?contentid=102639&lan=EN<br />

917 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Hungary <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Hungary<br />

918 EEA (2009) Diverting <strong>Waste</strong> from Landfill: Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Policies in the<br />

European Union, EEA Report No 7.<br />

919 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Italy <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008, http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Italy


The objectives <strong>of</strong> the waste tax are the prevention <strong>of</strong> waste production and the<br />

material and energy recovery from waste. The tax is calculated on the basis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

weight <strong>of</strong> the waste disposed at landfills or at incineration plants without energy<br />

recovery. The law also established a tax level between a minimum and maximum. For<br />

the first year (1996) the tax level was applied at the minimum level: this tax level is<br />

applied in every case in which the competent regional administration has not yet<br />

implemented a landfill tax. Currently there is a tax on MSW only, and can be set<br />

between 10€ and 50€. At least 20% <strong>of</strong> the tax revenue is required to be used by the<br />

local administration (the region) to finance environmental projects, such as:<br />

745<br />

1. <strong>Waste</strong> prevention;<br />

2. Projects on recycling and recovery <strong>of</strong> materials and energy from waste;<br />

3. Reclamation <strong>of</strong> contaminated sites and abandoned industrial sites;<br />

4. Recovery <strong>of</strong> degraded sites;<br />

5. Financing <strong>of</strong> the regional environmental protection agencies; and<br />

6. Institution and maintenance <strong>of</strong> protected natural areas.<br />

Only 10% <strong>of</strong> revenues are destined for the Provincial Government.<br />

The detailed structure <strong>of</strong> the tax is delegated to the competent regional<br />

administrations, which have the possibility to change three important elements:<br />

1. The tax level;<br />

2. The types <strong>of</strong> waste to which the tax applies; and<br />

3. Then uses to which the tax revenue will be devoted.<br />

Some regions have established – through regional acts – an increase in the tax if<br />

targets for separate collection are not achieved.<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> the landfill ban is to divert certain waste streams from landfill to other<br />

options, and to decrease the amount <strong>of</strong> waste landfilled. The material streams that<br />

are included are mainly as prescribed under the Landfill Directive, but also include<br />

the following:<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> containing or contaminated by PCBs, PCTs, and the like with<br />

concentrations > 25 ppm;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> containing or contaminated by PCDD or PCDF, with concentration > 10<br />

ppb;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> containing Ozone layer depleting substances;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> containing substances from research activities, with unknown effects<br />

on human health and the environment;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> with a Calorific Value > 13,000 kJ/kg, from 1/1/2007, however this<br />

was later postponed.<br />

A particular aspect <strong>of</strong> the Italian taxation policy is that once the policy had been<br />

implemented regional <strong>of</strong>fices are able to increase the tax level within bands initially<br />

set by central government to suit local circumstances. This gives an indication <strong>of</strong> the<br />

awareness <strong>of</strong> local issues and an ability to act flexibly at regional level.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


52.2.4.8 Country-specific Characteristics: Belgium (Flanders Region)<br />

The Flemish policies are described in Annex 54.0 below.<br />

52.2.4.9 Belgium (Wallonia Region)<br />

In Wallonia, , , the Decrees <strong>of</strong> 18 March 2004 and 30 March 2006 by the Walloon<br />

Government provide for a phased introduction <strong>of</strong> landfill bans. Table 52-2 presents a<br />

general summary <strong>of</strong> this phasing. Article 3 <strong>of</strong> the decree likewise provides that a pretreatment<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste materials, in order to sorting out <strong>of</strong> the reusable fractions, must<br />

be carried out before the waste can be landfilled.<br />

Of specific importance is Article 5 <strong>of</strong> the decree that provides for deviations in case <strong>of</strong><br />

force majeure and in exceptional circumstances. The shortage <strong>of</strong> adequate treatment<br />

facilities in Wallonia is explicitly acknowledged as an exceptional circumstance. The<br />

application for a deviation needs to be sufficiently justified and the licensing<br />

authority, the ‘Office Wallon des Déchets’ (OWD), the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Materials,<br />

shall impose demands relating to the landfill and the requirement to look for<br />

alternative treatment possibilities in the future.<br />

Table 52-2: Summary <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Ban in the Walloon Region<br />

Date Date <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> implementation implementation implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

the the landfill landfill ban<br />

ban<br />

1 July 2004<br />

1 January 2007<br />

1 January 2008<br />

746<br />

29/09/09<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> flows flows flows<br />

Comments<br />

Comments<br />

Separated household<br />

waste and non-hazardous<br />

industrial waste, e.g.<br />

organic waste, paper and<br />

cardboard, timber waste.<br />

Packaging waste<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> from pre-treatment<br />

and sorting facility<br />

Non-pre- treated fine<br />

residual household waste<br />

and non-shredded bulky<br />

waste<br />

1 January 2010 Shredded bulky waste<br />

Art. 2i <strong>of</strong> the Decree<br />

Source: OVAM (2007) Market Study <strong>of</strong> the Final Treatment <strong>of</strong> Residual Household<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> and Industrial <strong>Waste</strong> Similar to Household <strong>Waste</strong> in Flanders and<br />

Neighbouring Regions: a Summary Report, August 2007.


52.2.4.10 Country-specific Characteristics: Denmark<br />

The Danish Environmental Protection Act Consolidated Act No. 753 <strong>of</strong> 25 August<br />

2001 contains provisions on the regulation <strong>of</strong> waste. 920 The Act states that the local<br />

(municipal) council shall be in charge <strong>of</strong> waste management.<br />

The following polices are in place in Denmark:<br />

747<br />

� A tax on waste, implemented 1987. The waste tax is differentiated so that it is<br />

most expensive to landfill waste, cheaper to incinerate it, and tax exempt to<br />

recycle it. No tax is levied on hazardous waste, contaminated soil or waste that<br />

is covered under the Statutory Order on biomass waste; and<br />

� A ban on the landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste suitable for incineration - implemented 1997.<br />

Each local council is responsible for establishing capacity for waste management and<br />

for providing information on how to dispose <strong>of</strong> the waste produced within the local<br />

council, irrespective <strong>of</strong> whether this waste originates at households or trade and<br />

industry.<br />

The incineration <strong>of</strong> municipal waste has a long history in Denmark; the first waste<br />

incinerator being built in 1903. 921 In 1993 it was decided that waste should be<br />

preferred to other sources <strong>of</strong> energy when producing heat as a by-product <strong>of</strong> electric<br />

generation, and in 2005, waste incineration, producing heat and electricity, supplied<br />

4% <strong>of</strong> the total energy consumption in Denmark. The energy-to-waste facilities are<br />

subject to a cost coverage principle, which means that they show neither a pr<strong>of</strong>it nor<br />

a loss. 922<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> in Denmark is subject to ‘flow control’ and is managed by not for pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

companies that deal with the incineration <strong>of</strong> waste and operation <strong>of</strong> district heating<br />

systems. There are approximately 40 inter-municipal waste management companies<br />

in Denmark. The companies operate so that any pr<strong>of</strong>it gained from selling waste heat<br />

is used to <strong>of</strong>f-set the costs <strong>of</strong> operating the plant. The remaining income is generated<br />

from gate fees charged by the plants. Gate fees are amongst the lowest in Europe,<br />

despite the existence <strong>of</strong> incineration taxes.<br />

The extensive district heating systems that are in place in the country already<br />

purchase heat on the open market, however, there are price ceilings placed on the<br />

sale <strong>of</strong> heat from EfW plants so as to protect the heat consumers, and to ensure the<br />

heat is generally the lowest regional price so as to encourage its use.<br />

Denmark has a general tax on waste that is split into three tiers and primarily has the<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> encouraging recycling. The lowest tier is for recycling and set at a zero charge.<br />

An incineration tax has been introduced to discourage its use in preference to<br />

920 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Hungary <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Hungary<br />

921 European Environment Agency (2007) The road from landfilling to recycling: common destination,<br />

different routes, http://reports.eea.europa.eu/brochure_2007_4<br />

922 RenoSam (2006) The Danish Model, News from DBDH<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


ecycling. Initially, the rates for landfilling and incineration were the same, but since<br />

1993, the levy has been differentiated (with a higher rate for landfilling). The tax rate<br />

is now set at € 44 /tonne. To be an effective deterrent from landfilling waste the<br />

landfill tax has been set higher at € 50.7 /tonne.<br />

As with incineration plants and district heating networks, new landfills must be owned<br />

by public authorities, and whoever operates a landfill site must ensure that all costs<br />

related to establishment and operation, including financial security and after-care <strong>of</strong><br />

the site <strong>of</strong> a period <strong>of</strong> at least 30 years are covered by the payment collected for<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong> the waste.<br />

In 1997, landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste suitable for incineration was banned. The aim was to<br />

move waste from landfill to incineration, and to ease the capacity demand on<br />

landfills. It has been reported that the regulation has been very successful in shifting<br />

waste from landfilling to incineration. 923<br />

The long history <strong>of</strong> incineration and the widespread district heat networks in Denmark<br />

have provided a context for the development <strong>of</strong> these policy measures. The view<br />

adopted is that heat is in demand, and where centralised sources are in place, it<br />

makes sense to use waste as the source <strong>of</strong> energy to generate that heat.<br />

52.2.4.11 France<br />

The French system is based on policies such as the Code de l’environnement (Partie<br />

législative) that defines waste disposal and recycling. 924 The instruments currently in<br />

place in France are:<br />

748<br />

� Landfill Tax implemented in 1992 and included in the General Tax on Polluting<br />

Activities (TGAP) from 1999. The aim is to prevent waste landfilling and to<br />

boost waste reduction and recycling, forms <strong>of</strong> waste management more<br />

compatible with the environment; and to fight against illegal practices;<br />

� Ban on Landfilling from 2002 - to divert critical waste flows from landfills.<br />

The 1975 law on <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal and Material Recovery (75-633) first stated the<br />

intention, through the French <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan, to ban all but so-called ‘final<br />

waste’ from landfill by 2002. However, no decisive action to implement this policy<br />

was taken.<br />

The policy was also meant to streamline French waste management, increase waste<br />

recovery rates to 50% and become part <strong>of</strong> a self-financing waste management<br />

strategy. Essentially the aim was to make landfilling totally unpopular on financial<br />

grounds by passing through the ‘price signal’ to landfill users. Indirectly it was also<br />

923 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Denmark <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Denmark<br />

924 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) France <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/France<br />

29/09/09


meant to finance the Modernisation Fund for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (MFWM) 925,<br />

created in 1993.<br />

The tax was introduced in 1993 at FRF 20 per tonne. The rate increased to FRF 60 (€<br />

9.15) per tonne in 1995, which is still the standard rate for municipal and<br />

comparable waste. Since 2003, sites with EMAS or ISO 14000 certification pay a<br />

reduced rate <strong>of</strong> € 7.50 per tonne. Non-authorised landfills pay a rate <strong>of</strong> € 36.58 per<br />

tonne <strong>of</strong> municipal waste, which is also the rate for special industrial waste. Since<br />

1999, the tax is part <strong>of</strong> the TGAP (Taxe Générale sur les Activités Polluantes) 926 .<br />

Initially the revenue was used to promote innovative methods <strong>of</strong> waste treatment and<br />

to equip local authorities with sufficient funds to;<br />

749<br />

� develop innovative technology for household and assimilated waste treatment;<br />

� install waste treatment facilities, especially those which make use <strong>of</strong><br />

innovative technology;<br />

� aid to local authorities on whose territory a new treatment plant for household<br />

and assimilated waste is built; and<br />

� aid the upgrading public landfill sites and restoring contaminated sites.<br />

Perhaps unsurprisingly, given the low rate <strong>of</strong> the tax, relatively little impact was felt<br />

from the tax measure. Hence, in 2002, a ban on untreated waste to landfills was<br />

introduced as part <strong>of</strong> the TGAP policy. This was to enable France to meet the EU<br />

landfill directive by reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong>, and level <strong>of</strong> biodegradability <strong>of</strong>, waste<br />

disposed <strong>of</strong> at landfill.<br />

The ban is intended to cover ‘ultimate wastes’. One study defines these as: 927<br />

ultimate waste flow as a waste flow that is no longer suitable to be treated under<br />

the current technical and ec economic ec onomic conditions, in particular, through recovering<br />

<strong>of</strong> the component part that can be revalued or by the reduction <strong>of</strong> its<br />

contaminated character.<br />

The same study notes that the ban is not really enforced in Nord Pas-de-Calais in<br />

France:<br />

Household and equivalent waste flows may, in principle, no longer be disposed <strong>of</strong><br />

on the landfill site. However, this ban is not strictly enforced because <strong>of</strong> the lack<br />

<strong>of</strong> adequate incineration capacity and the importance that NPDC attaches to the<br />

925 The MFWM was run by the ADEME to support investments in local communities’ related to (1)<br />

innovative household/assimilated waste treatment equipment (development or setting-up); (2) the<br />

upgrading <strong>of</strong> landfill sites; (3) remediation <strong>of</strong> contaminated sites; and (4) new treatment facilities.<br />

926 ECOTEC (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.<br />

927 OVAM (2007) Market Study <strong>of</strong> the Final Treatment <strong>of</strong> Residual Household <strong>Waste</strong> and Industrial<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Similar to Household <strong>Waste</strong> in Flanders and Neighbouring Regions: a Summary Report, August<br />

2007.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


750<br />

proximity principle. Furthermore, the definition <strong>of</strong> ultimate residual flow leaves<br />

room for interpretation.<br />

The situation in France is interesting because <strong>of</strong> the high level <strong>of</strong> illegal dumping sites<br />

that were present at the time <strong>of</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> the tax. The local authorities<br />

continued to tax them without forcing closure or licensing. The landfill ban,<br />

implemented several years later, may well have been developed to strengthen the<br />

seemingly weak effects <strong>of</strong> the tax.<br />

52.2.4.12 The Netherlands<br />

The Environmental <strong>Management</strong> Act (1993) introduced an integrated approach to<br />

environmental issues, and sought to account for their interrelationships. 928 The main<br />

features were that it elaborated a hierarchy <strong>of</strong> management options based on<br />

Lansink’s Ladder, and made separate collection <strong>of</strong> organic household waste<br />

compulsory.<br />

In 1996, simultaneously, two instruments were implemented:<br />

� A tax on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste – aimed at making disposal the lest attractive<br />

option economically; and<br />

� A ban on landfilling covering 35 categories <strong>of</strong> combustible or recyclable<br />

wastes.<br />

The sequence <strong>of</strong> events is set out as below:<br />

Landfill bans;<br />

- 1995: Publication <strong>of</strong> the Decree on a Ban <strong>of</strong> Landfill <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

- 1995-1999: Ministerial decrees that regulate that the Decree is applicable to<br />

specific waste streams that were exempted when the Decree was first<br />

published. For many waste streams the Decree went into force directly.<br />

However, for some waste streams no treatment technology or enough capacity<br />

was available. Once a relatively cost-effective technology became available,<br />

landfill <strong>of</strong> a specific stream would be banned.<br />

- 1997: Publication <strong>of</strong> a Decree on Landfills and Ban on Landfill <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, that<br />

combines the Decree <strong>of</strong> 1995 with another Decree that arranged permitting<br />

procedures for landfills 929 .<br />

- Related EU Directives: 1999/31/EC (L182, 16.7.1999), Directive on Landfill<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> and 2003/33/EC (PbEG L11, 16.1.2003) on Criteria and procedures<br />

on the acceptance <strong>of</strong> waste on landfills<br />

Landfill taxes;<br />

928 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Netherlands <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Netherlands<br />

929 See: http://wetten.overheid.nl/cgi-bin/sessioned/browsercheck/continuation=29495-<br />

002/session=532342511010954/action=javascript-result/javascript=yes (accessed 23 March 2006)<br />

29/09/09


751<br />

- 1995: Publication <strong>of</strong> a regulation on the basis <strong>of</strong> the Law Environmental Taxes<br />

- 1995-now: various changes in the taxation level to the level in force now<br />

(84,78 Euro per ton for incinerable waste and 13,98 Euro per ton for other<br />

waste) 930<br />

The waste tax covers the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste to landfill and incineration. 931 The level <strong>of</strong><br />

taxation for incineration was, however, set at zero and is remains at this level to this<br />

day. The landfill tax was introduced at a level <strong>of</strong> NLG 29.20 (€13.25) per tonne.<br />

After 1997 two bands were introduced specifying rates for combustible and noncombustible<br />

wastes. Its current rate, since 2005, is € 84.78 per tonne for<br />

combustible wastes. The rate for non-combustibles is € 13.98 per tonne, the same<br />

rate applying to certain other categories <strong>of</strong> waste, including hazardous waste and<br />

waste with a density <strong>of</strong> more than 1,100 kg per m 3 (typically, inert materials). 932 The<br />

evolution in these rates is shown in Figure 52-2.<br />

Figure 52-2: Changes in Dutch Landfill Tax since Implementation<br />

Tax Rate, €<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Changes in Dutch Landfill Tax since Implementation<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

Year<br />

Year<br />

Combusitble<br />

Non-combustible<br />

930 See<br />

http://www.minfin.nl/default.asp?CMS_ITEM=MFCWD970934C51F83449B932D1E9D4D61AF6DX22<br />

X55355X16#afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen (accessed March 22, 2006).<br />

931 European Commission (2008) “Taxes in Europe” database, Accessed 12 th October 2008,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/taxinv/welcome.do;jsessionid=LZJpKGQB7ZRrngVLZhhS5cx7w<br />

CkJBrCFL21f5r9t65bYTG6JhKQ5!-966966153<br />

932 ECOTEC (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.


A general ban on recyclable and combustible waste was introduced in 1996. 933 The<br />

ban covers around 35 material streams and includes organic and household waste,<br />

paper & card, tyres, ELVs, batteries and various hazardous wastes. The purpose was<br />

to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> waste being landfilled.<br />

The ban was introduced in the context <strong>of</strong> the dioxin emissions scandal in the late<br />

1980s. The Dutch were rebuilding their incineration capacity with much higher<br />

pollution control mechanisms, and regulatory measures were needed to ensure that<br />

incineration capacity would be used, and hence, that the high investment cost would<br />

not be wasted.<br />

The amount <strong>of</strong> waste generated in the Netherlands has been reported as ‘decoupled’<br />

from Gross Domestic Product (GDP) since 2000. 934 The amount <strong>of</strong> waste landfilled<br />

halved from 1995-2003. For incineration, the opposite trend was observed. The total<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> waste incinerated in 1995 was 4.8 Mt and in 2003 it had increased to 8.2<br />

Mt. As the incineration capacity remained constant over this period, as reported in the<br />

IVM study below, the remaining waste was exported for incineration:<br />

752<br />

29/09/09<br />

‘In 1995 and 1996 the last incineration plants were built, and from that time<br />

the government maintained a moratorium for ‘traditional’ grate incineration<br />

plants. New plants using more energy efficient technologies (such as coincineration<br />

or gasification) were allowed, but no new incineration plants<br />

became operational until 2003. So, the total number <strong>of</strong> waste incineration<br />

plants was constant at 11 in the period 1997-2003’.<br />

In certain areas incineration capacity was limited so a number <strong>of</strong> waste producers<br />

were unable to dispose <strong>of</strong> their combustible wastes thus exemptions were made so<br />

that operators could continue to landfill waste so that it was not illegally dumped. As<br />

the incineration capacity increased (to around 5.4 Mt), and the export <strong>of</strong> waste was<br />

unconstrained due to the harmonisation <strong>of</strong> waste trading via the European <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Shipment Regulation (WSR, 259/93), exemptions became harder to obtain.<br />

The main purpose <strong>of</strong> these policies was to shift waste from landfill and to ensure<br />

continued supply for the national incineration plants so that the capital expenditure<br />

outlaid in upgrading them was not wasted. This is why waste has been categorised<br />

into combustible and non-combustible fractions for the purpose <strong>of</strong> the ban and the<br />

landfill levy. This classification is meaningless in countries that are not advocating<br />

widespread EfW use, and may be counterproductive from an environmental<br />

perspective.<br />

Other points to note about The Netherlands are; that there is a general good<br />

awareness <strong>of</strong> the environment and waste related issues will be <strong>of</strong> social importance;<br />

but also that the swift implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax and ban led to under-capacity <strong>of</strong><br />

933 Eunomia et al (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report<br />

for Defra.<br />

934 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.


esidual treatments, and thus exemptions were needed to allow licensed disposal in<br />

landfill.<br />

52.2.4.13 Norway<br />

A waste disposal tax was introduced in Norway in 1999. This was to reduce methane<br />

emissions from landfill and incentivise the recovery <strong>of</strong> energy produced during<br />

incineration, hence reducing the environmental damage caused by final waste<br />

treatment.<br />

The landfill tax was introduced at around 40 € for those landfills with a high<br />

environmental performance, and at a slightly higher rate for those which fell below<br />

this level. The incineration tax was initially set at the same level as for landfilling<br />

where there was no energy recovery. The tax level drops as a greater proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

energy is recovered from the process. Since 1999 new laws have been included that<br />

introduce tax rebates for landfill operators who recover and sell energy generated<br />

from the methane gas captured.<br />

The incineration tax has also been changed to reward operators who reduce pollution<br />

below legal limits specified in the EU’s 2001 <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration Directive. This is<br />

done by changing the mechanism so that it is emissions based and focuses on<br />

pollutants such as CO2, NOx, SOx, particulates and dioxins. The CO2 charge (€4.85) is<br />

per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste delivered to an incineration plant, and all the additional 14<br />

pollutants are taxed on the basis <strong>of</strong> the quantity <strong>of</strong> pollutant emitted. The changes<br />

were introduced in such a way that the overall revenue take would be more or less<br />

unchanged, and so that no major change to the balance <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatments<br />

would be occasioned by this.<br />

Norway has announced a ban on the landfilling <strong>of</strong> biodegradable wastes which is due<br />

to take effect very shortly. There was some debate as to whether the policy <strong>of</strong> choice<br />

should be an outright ban, or whether the policy should be more in line with the<br />

German and Austrian restrictions, but the outcome appears to have favoured a tighter<br />

approach.<br />

52.2.4.14 Sweden<br />

The Swedish policies stem from the Environment Act (1998:808) and the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Regulation (2001:1063). 935 The relevant policies are:<br />

753<br />

� A tax on landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste from 2000 - to make landfilling a less attractive<br />

option and to increase the economic incentives to reduce waste amounts, and<br />

use waste treatment methods that are preferable from environmental and<br />

natural resources perspectives;<br />

� A ban on landfilling – introduced in 2002 for combustible wastes, and<br />

amended in 2005 to include compostable wastes; and<br />

935 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Sweden <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Sweden<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


754<br />

� A tax on incineration from 2006 - modelled on the fossil carbon content <strong>of</strong> fuel<br />

and on the level <strong>of</strong> electrical generation.<br />

The Swedish landfill tax was introduced in 2000 at a rate <strong>of</strong> about € 27 (250 SEK)<br />

per tonne. The primary aim was to halve the amount <strong>of</strong> waste landfilled by 2005 from<br />

1994. 936 In 2002 the rate was increased, and also again in 2006, to the current level<br />

<strong>of</strong> around € 45.5 (435 SEK). The tax is designed so that all waste going to landfill is<br />

taxed. <strong>Waste</strong> that exits a landfill or is used as construction material qualifies for a tax<br />

reduction. <strong>Waste</strong> for which no treatment method (other than landfilling) is applicable<br />

is also subject to tax.<br />

Concurrently with the tax increase in 2002, a ban on sorted combustible waste was<br />

introduced. The purpose <strong>of</strong> this was to reduce the environmental impacts associated<br />

with landfilling and increase resource efficiency. In 2005 the ban was extended to<br />

include all organic wastes. Certain types <strong>of</strong> waste are exempted from the ban, for<br />

example, waste with a Total Organic Content (TOC) <strong>of</strong> less than 10% (dry matter).<br />

The capacity <strong>of</strong> Swedish incinerators increased substantially between 1996 and<br />

2002. 937 Much <strong>of</strong> this was due to the substantial district heating systems already in<br />

place whereby the source <strong>of</strong> the heat was switched from fossil fuels to waste-derived<br />

incineration plants, some operating as CHP facilities, others operating with heat-only<br />

boilers (HOB). One <strong>of</strong> the main drivers for this change was the Swedish energy policy<br />

that gives incentives for the use <strong>of</strong> energy derived from waste, over fossil fuels, via<br />

the economic instrument <strong>of</strong> taxation. 938 In total, 30 MSW incineration plants exist in<br />

Sweden; 16 are CHP plants, 13 are HOB, and one plant delivers steam to an<br />

industrial user. 939<br />

A tax on waste-to-energy incineration <strong>of</strong> municipal solid waste (MSW) was introduced<br />

on July 1, 2006. The was designed to give CHP plants an advantage compared with<br />

HOB, but also to increase the incentive for material recycling, including biological<br />

treatment, and to effectively align the taxation <strong>of</strong> incineration with the energy taxation<br />

system, where incineration <strong>of</strong> wastes <strong>of</strong> fossil origin was not burdened with energy<br />

and CO2 taxation as other fossil fuels are. 940<br />

The amount <strong>of</strong> the tax is calculated based on a model <strong>of</strong> the content <strong>of</strong> fossil material<br />

in the waste. 941 The amount <strong>of</strong> the tax is dependent on whether the taxable<br />

936 OECD (2004) Environmental Performance <strong>Review</strong>s: Sweden. Paris: OECD.<br />

937 European Environment Agency (2007) The road from landfilling to recycling: common destination,<br />

different routes, http://reports.eea.europa.eu/brochure_2007_4<br />

938 T. Ekvall, M. Ol<strong>of</strong>sson, J. Sahlin and J. Sundberg (2005) Driving forces for import <strong>of</strong> waste for energy<br />

recovery in Sweden, http://www.bvsde.paho.org/bvsacd/cd43/matias.pdf<br />

939 Avfall Sverige (2008) Swedish <strong>Waste</strong> Mangement,<br />

http://www.avfallsverige.se/se/netset/files3/web/P01.m4n?download=true&id=2371_94867351<br />

940 Swedish Ministry <strong>of</strong> Finance (2006) Proposition 2005/06:125 Beskattning av visst hushållsavfall<br />

som förbränns, m.m. (Taxation <strong>of</strong> some household waste for incineration), Ministry <strong>of</strong> Finance, 2006<br />

941 Avfall Sverige (2008) Swedish <strong>Waste</strong> Mangement,<br />

http://www.avfallsverige.se/se/netset/files3/web/P01.m4n?download=true&id=2371_94867351<br />

29/09/09


incineration facilities produce electricity and, if so, how efficiently. For facilities<br />

without electrical production, the tax is € 49 (SEK 487) per tonne, which would then<br />

decrease with increased electricity production. At 15 per cent electricity production,<br />

the tax is approx. € 8.3 (SEK 83) per tonne, at 20 per cent approx € 7.6 (SEK 76) per<br />

tonne. After the introduction <strong>of</strong> the tax material recycling, including biological<br />

treatment, has increased from 34.6 per cent to 48.7 per cent and waste -to-energy<br />

has increased from 38.1 to 46.4 per cent.<br />

As with other Northern European countries there are substantial district heating<br />

systems in place in Sweden. The evolution <strong>of</strong> the policies have been firstly to reduce<br />

landfilling and to promote the use <strong>of</strong> RDF as a fuel for the heating systems, then to<br />

incentivise more efficient operation <strong>of</strong> incinerators and moreover to promote<br />

materials recycling and MBT facilities as they become economically viable. In all<br />

cases the costs <strong>of</strong> disposal <strong>of</strong> the least attractive options was made more expensive.<br />

Both the landfill ban <strong>of</strong> waste with TOC greater than 10% and the incineration tax<br />

based on fossil carbon content require measurements or assumptions to be made<br />

regarding these values. This could make the implementation and monitoring <strong>of</strong> the<br />

systems more difficult to manage.<br />

52.2.4.15 Czech Republic<br />

Act 188/2004 Coll. Is the implementing policy in the Czech Republic that deals with<br />

the handling and disposal <strong>of</strong> wastes. 942 Policies in place are:<br />

755<br />

� A levy on landfilling introduced in 1991. The holder <strong>of</strong> waste pays a levy when<br />

depositing waste in a landfill. This fee consists <strong>of</strong> two components:<br />

• the basic fee; and<br />

• the risk-based fee.<br />

The basic fee applies to all categories <strong>of</strong> waste (and is differentiated into two<br />

levels, one for municipal and other non-hazardous waste, and the other for<br />

hazardous waste). The risk component <strong>of</strong> the fee is paid only for hazardous<br />

waste. The operator <strong>of</strong> the landfill transfers the collected revenue to the<br />

collectors, i.e. the municipality in whose cadastre the landfill is located (basic<br />

component) and SEF CR (risk component). The basic fee, that includes<br />

municipal waste, has risen steadily since implementation, and is now at €16<br />

per tonne, and is set to rise 25% to €20 in 2009.<br />

52.2.4.16 Estonia<br />

The relevant legislation is the <strong>Waste</strong> Act (RT1 I 2004, 9, 52) 2004. 943 Its main<br />

features are:<br />

942 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Czech Republic<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Czech_Republic<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


756<br />

� Landfills are classified according to EU framework (Art 34, <strong>Waste</strong> Act); and<br />

� A prohibition on the deposit <strong>of</strong> untreated waste in landfills (Art 35, <strong>Waste</strong> Act)<br />

The two policy instruments that are important are:<br />

� A levy on municipal waste disposal implemented in 1990. The aim was<br />

promotion <strong>of</strong> waste recovery, and for the financing <strong>of</strong> waste management<br />

projects via Environment Investment Centre and local budgets. However, the<br />

rates are very low. At the time <strong>of</strong> first implementation, the levy was set at only<br />

€ 0.10, per tonne but this has now risen to a current level <strong>of</strong> €8 per tonne; and<br />

� A ban on unsorted waste from landfilling, was applied in 2008.<br />

There were a large number <strong>of</strong> small illegal landfills in Estonia in the late 1990’s<br />

mainly due to a lack <strong>of</strong> sound collection and recycling infrastructure. Since then, most<br />

have closed and several modern, large-scale landfills have opened with EU funding.<br />

However, only one <strong>of</strong> these is equipped with landfill gas capture.<br />

The levy rates were initially kept low so as to not stimulate an increase in illegal<br />

dumping on ‘waste fields’ (areas covered with 1-2m <strong>of</strong> residual bin waste). The<br />

municipal infrastructure has increased and now waste generators are charged € 8<br />

per tonne on new landfills and €16 per tonne on ‘old ones’. The landfill tax is thought<br />

to be a ‘very powerful instrument’ and is expected to be raised significantly over the<br />

next few years. 944 The plan is to reduce the number <strong>of</strong> landfills to 3-4 in the long-term.<br />

The implementation <strong>of</strong> the ban is not entirely straightforward. The EEA states:<br />

29/09/09<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> Act (2004) introduced a ban on landfilling untreated waste<br />

(including mixed municipal waste). However, until 1 January 2008 it only<br />

applied to landfills in counties that had an established facility for treating<br />

municipal waste. In reality, only the landfills in the Harju County (in Tallinn<br />

area) met this requirement.<br />

52.2.4.17 Slovakia<br />

In Slovakia a charge for deposition <strong>of</strong> waste to landfills was introduced in 1992. 945 It<br />

was updated in 2004 and includes scheduled increases from 2008. The revenues<br />

are earmarked for the protection <strong>of</strong> the environment in the relevant municipality, and<br />

must be used for waste management purposes only.<br />

943 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Estonia <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Estonia<br />

944 P. Eek – <strong>Waste</strong> Depertment, Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment <strong>of</strong> Estonia (2008) Implementation <strong>of</strong> EU<br />

Landfill Directive in Estonia, Presentation given in 2008,<br />

www.rec.org/REC/Programs/REREP/PEIP/docs/national_workshop...14/.../waste_2.3_p-eek-landfill landfilldir-impl-ee-_budva-14-05-08.ppt<br />

945 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Slovakia <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Slovakia


There are several bands in this tax system, which include hazardous, inert and<br />

municipal waste streams. The level <strong>of</strong> taxation for MSW decreases as components<br />

are removed for recycling i.e., if there is a collection system in place that removes 2<br />

components such as paper and glass, the tax will be lower than for the residual<br />

stream. This is most likely to incentivise the uptake <strong>of</strong> collection systems for<br />

recyclables. The rates applicable are shown in Table 52-3.<br />

Table 52-3: Landfill Tax Rates in Slovakia<br />

757<br />

Material Material Stream Stream<br />

Tax Tax Rate, Rate, Rate, € per tonne<br />

Hazardous <strong>Waste</strong> 26.3<br />

Inert <strong>Waste</strong> 0.26<br />

MSW with no separation 7.89<br />

MSW with 1 component separated 7.10<br />

MSW with 2 components separated 6.32<br />

MSW with 3 components separated 5.53<br />

MSW with 4 components separated 4.74<br />

MSW with 5 components separated 3.95<br />

Other <strong>Waste</strong> 5.26<br />

Green <strong>Waste</strong> 10.53<br />

52.2.4.18 Slovenia<br />

The Environment Protection Act provides the basis for the following policies: 946<br />

� A ban on landfilling introduced in 2001 for the purposes <strong>of</strong> limiting organic<br />

waste going to landfill; and<br />

� A tax on landfill introduced in 2001, for sanitation, technical adjustment <strong>of</strong><br />

the landfill, construction or purchasing <strong>of</strong> equipment. The tax must be paid by<br />

the operator.<br />

The landfill ban currently includes:<br />

946 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Slovenia <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Slovenia<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


758<br />

� Liquid waste, infectious waste, explosive waste;<br />

� Tyres; and<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> which does not meet the acceptance criteria depending on landfill type<br />

i.e. regulates biodegradable and hazardous waste.<br />

Since 2001, when the Decree on Environmental Tax for Environmental Pollution<br />

Caused by <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal was adopted, all landfill operators <strong>of</strong> hazardous, nonhazardous<br />

and inert landfill are obliged to pay tax on the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste. If the<br />

operator invests the collected revenue in improved sanitation and technical<br />

upgrading <strong>of</strong> the landfill, or in construction, or in purchasing <strong>of</strong> equipment, then the<br />

Ministry for Environmental and Spatial Planning- Environmental Agency <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Republic <strong>of</strong> Slovenia confirms the investments, and the operator is not obliged to<br />

transfer the collected tax revenue to the state budget.<br />

Since 2001, the investments in public infrastructure (landfilling <strong>of</strong> municipal waste)<br />

increased annually to €13 million per annum. The largest share was spent on landfills<br />

for municipal waste and for hazardous waste, with significant investment also into<br />

collection and recycling schemes.<br />

52.2.4.19 Spain (Catalonia)<br />

Taxes for Landfills are not generally implemented in Spain. However, Madrid does<br />

have taxes for hazardous waste (€ 10 per tonne), domestic waste (€7 per tonne) and<br />

C&D waste (€3 per tonne). 947<br />

In the region <strong>of</strong> Catalonia, there is also a landfill tax. The tax is levied on the sending<br />

<strong>of</strong> municipal waste to waste disposal facilities controlled by public or private sector<br />

located in Catalonia. The taxpayers are the local authorities that operate, or contract<br />

out the operation <strong>of</strong>, the municipal waste management service, and municipal waste<br />

producers. The tax is implemented at the time the holder delivers the waste to the<br />

landfill and at the point where the facility operator accepts it.<br />

The tax rate is €10 per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste sent to landfill for municipalities with separate<br />

biowaste collection, and €20 per tonne for those that do not, and is adjusted annually<br />

by means <strong>of</strong> the Catalan Finance Act. 948<br />

Also in Catalonia, from 2008, an incineration tax has been implemented, the first <strong>of</strong><br />

its kind in Spain. The tax rate will be €5 per tonne. However, there will be an<br />

increased tax rate <strong>of</strong> €15 per tonne for those municipalities that do not have in place<br />

separate collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste, but could have introduced it according to the regional<br />

waste strategy.<br />

At least 50% <strong>of</strong> the revenue generated must be used to reduce the cost for<br />

municipalities <strong>of</strong> managing biowaste coming from household source separation, or to<br />

947 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Spain <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008, http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Spain<br />

948 Agencia de Residus de Catalunya website (2008) <strong>Waste</strong> disposal tax, Accessed on 23 rd October<br />

2008, http://www.arc.cat/en/municipals/canon/index.html<br />

29/09/09


educe the quantity, or improve the quality <strong>of</strong> refuse, especially reducing the presence<br />

<strong>of</strong> organic materials. The remaining revenue must be dedicated to the separate<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> biowaste, and the separate collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> other waste<br />

fractions, or to other forms <strong>of</strong> valorisation or to awareness-raising campaigns.<br />

The rates applicable for refunds (for 2008) are shown in Table 52-4.<br />

Table 52-4: Refund Rates Used in Catalunya<br />

Concept Concept Concept<br />

Rate Rate<br />

Rate<br />

1. Biowaste treatment 33.5 €/tonne<br />

2. Treatments to reduce the quantity or improve the quality <strong>of</strong><br />

refuse<br />

5 €/tonne<br />

3. Biowaste separate collection* 12 €/tonne<br />

4. Paper/cardboard separate collection 21 €/tonne<br />

5. Active recycling centre in the municipality<br />

5.1 Per inhabitant:**<br />

5.2 Per tonne:<br />

0.32<br />

€/inhabitant<br />

Wood 12 €/tonne<br />

Flat glass 12 €/tonne<br />

Batteries 160 €/tonne<br />

Vegetal oil<br />

* Quantities are considered net <strong>of</strong> impurities.<br />

** A correction factor is applied in municipalities with high seasonal population.<br />

80 €/tonne<br />

The rate for concept 3 is multiplied by a coefficient dependent on the level <strong>of</strong><br />

impurities in the collected biowaste. In addition, the rates for concepts 3, 4 and 5.1<br />

are adjusted using the coefficients that are based on the size <strong>of</strong> the municipality.<br />

These criteria are revised annually, and will continue to be so, since the revenue from<br />

the tax depends on waste generation and recycling levels, which vary from year to<br />

year.<br />

52.2.4.20 United Kingdom<br />

The principle instruments <strong>of</strong> interest in the UK are:<br />

759<br />

� The landfill tax – implemented in 1996 to encourage a reduction in landfill <strong>of</strong><br />

waste and promote recycling, and also to raise revenue. The tax on municipal<br />

waste is paid by households and local authorities and the tax on commercial<br />

and industrial waste streams are paid by business sectors;<br />

� The Landfill Allowance Schemes (LAS) – introduced in 2005 to meet the<br />

landfill targets for reduction <strong>of</strong> BMW (See Section 55.0);<br />

� A ban on landfilling <strong>of</strong> certain animal wastes as part <strong>of</strong> the ABP regulations<br />

implemented in 2003 (though this has effectively not been introduced); and<br />

� A ban on hazardous waste disposed <strong>of</strong> at non-hazardous landfills by 2004, a<br />

ban on the landfilling <strong>of</strong> used tyres from 2006, and a ban on landfilling <strong>of</strong><br />

liquid wastes from Oct 2007 (to meet requirements <strong>of</strong> the EU Landfill<br />

Directive).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The UK Landfill Tax was introduced in October 1996. It is a tax on all landfilled waste,<br />

with some exemptions. It is applied at two rates: a standard rate, applied to a range<br />

<strong>of</strong> materials, including household waste; and a lower rate, applying to specific<br />

‘qualifying materials’, typically, those deemed to be ‘inert’, including materials such<br />

as rubble.<br />

The tax affects all sectors <strong>of</strong> the economy. As the levels <strong>of</strong> landfilling at the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> the tax were very high, the tax could be considered a ‘general disposal<br />

tax’, as most residual waste was (and still is) disposed <strong>of</strong> to landfill.<br />

The aims <strong>of</strong> the tax as set out in the UK <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy were:<br />

760<br />

29/09/09<br />

‘to ensure that landfill costs reflect environmental impact thereby encouraging<br />

business and consumers, in a cost effective and non regulatory manner, to<br />

produce less waste; to recover value from more <strong>of</strong> the waste that is produced;<br />

and to dispose <strong>of</strong> less waste in landfill sites (DoE and WO 1995, 12).’<br />

From this, it seems clear that the primary aim was, in the early stages, to internalise<br />

external environmental impacts.<br />

Ecotec’s report on taxes and charges in the EU indicates that the tax level and the<br />

proposals for the tax were widely consulted on before being introduced. 949 The initial<br />

rates at which the tax was set were:<br />

� Inert <strong>Waste</strong>s (lower rate tax) £2 per tonne<br />

� Active <strong>Waste</strong>s (standard rate tax) £7 per tonne.<br />

Mixed wastes are taxed as active wastes even if much <strong>of</strong> the material is ‘inert’ if<br />

certain minimal levels <strong>of</strong> mixing are exceeded.<br />

A report describes how the tax has evolved as follows: 950<br />

� 1993 – The introduction <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Tax was preceded by an assessment <strong>of</strong><br />

the external costs associated with landfill and incineration and by work<br />

assessing waste management options in the UK after the introduction <strong>of</strong> such<br />

a tax. 951 A proposal for a tax based on a percentage <strong>of</strong> disposal costs (an ad<br />

valorem tax) emerged, with the order <strong>of</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> the tax heavily<br />

influenced by the external costs study;<br />

� November 1994 – Government makes clear its intention to introduce the<br />

Landfill Tax;<br />

� March 1995 - a consultation process was undertaken to elicit the views <strong>of</strong><br />

industry, environmentalists, and local authorities. Its major outcome, as<br />

949 ECOTEC (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.<br />

950 Eunomia et al (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report<br />

for Defra<br />

951 CSERGE, Warren Spring Laboratory and EFTEL (1993) Externalities for Landfill and Incineration: A<br />

Study by CSERGE, Warren Spring Laboratory and EFTEL. Coopers & Lybrand (1993) Landfill Costs and<br />

Prices: Correcting Possible Market Distortions.


761<br />

announced in the November 1995 Budget, was a change in the tax design,<br />

from a percentage <strong>of</strong> disposal cost (ad valorem) system, to a weight-based tax.<br />

Furthermore, it was intended that there should be no exemptions from the tax;<br />

and<br />

� November 1995 – Budget announces the tax will be introduced in October<br />

1996.<br />

At the outset typical disposal fees pre-tax for municipal wastes, or non-inert industrial<br />

wastes, were between £7-£25 (approx €11.20-€40.00) per tonne so that the tax<br />

implied an increase in price <strong>of</strong> between 30-100%. The level <strong>of</strong> taxation for non-inert<br />

wastes (i.e. those that degrade to produce GHGs) was increased by the method <strong>of</strong> an<br />

annual price escalator that was first introduced in 1998. Since then the magnitude <strong>of</strong><br />

the escalator has increased (initial £1 per tonne escalator over five years to current<br />

£8 per tonne per year over 6 years). As <strong>of</strong> April 2009, the tax rate is £40 (approx.<br />

€50) per tonne. The tax will rise to a maximum level <strong>of</strong> £72 per tonne in April 2013.<br />

The tax rate for inert wastes has remained relatively steady with only a 50p increase<br />

to £2.50 per tonne in 2007.<br />

Implemented through central government via the Chancellor <strong>of</strong> the Exchequer (HM<br />

Treasury) and the annual budget, Figure 52-3 shows the change in tax levels for<br />

active and inert wastes from the implementation <strong>of</strong> the policy in 1996 to 2013 when<br />

the current escalator expires.<br />

Figure 52-3: English Landfill Tax (£/tonne)<br />

Tax Rate, £<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Changes in England's Landfill Tax since Implementation<br />

1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013<br />

Year<br />

Year<br />

Active Rate<br />

Inert Rate<br />

The revenues generated from the tax were initially used to allow for a decrease in the<br />

national insurance rate, along with a scheme to fund waste management research<br />

and improvement projects around landfills. Those wishing to utilize the funds had to<br />

register as environmental bodies under an organization named ENTRUST.<br />

With the end <strong>of</strong> this scheme some 4-5 years ago the funds are now directed to the<br />

Landfill Communities Fund, WRAP, LASU, WIP and various other Defra schemes under


the heading <strong>of</strong> the Business Resource Efficiency and <strong>Waste</strong> (BREW) programme.<br />

Since its launch, 12 years ago, the landfill tax has raised over £700m for these types<br />

<strong>of</strong> projects that benefit the environment. 952<br />

52.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

52.3.1 Levies<br />

Table 52-5 below shows examples for certain countries considered in this section <strong>of</strong><br />

the report, to give an indication <strong>of</strong> the types <strong>of</strong> organisations involved. These are<br />

generally environmental agencies and also, revenue collection authorities (regional or<br />

national) to ensure collection <strong>of</strong> revenues. It was not thought necessary to include all<br />

the countries described in this section <strong>of</strong> the report.<br />

Table 52-5: Organisations Involved in Implementation and <strong>Management</strong><br />

762<br />

29/09/09<br />

Country Country Country<br />

Key Key Key Organisations<br />

Organisations<br />

Organisations<br />

� Rate: HM Treasury (input from Defra)<br />

England<br />

� Collection: HM Revenue and Customs<br />

� Rate: Ministry <strong>of</strong> Finance, Section Excise and Duty<br />

� National Agency for Environment and Energy<br />

France<br />

<strong>Management</strong> (ADEME)<br />

� Collection:<br />

� Rate:<br />

The Netherlands � Collection:<br />

� VROM (Ministry <strong>of</strong> the environment)<br />

� Finnish Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment<br />

Finland<br />

� Collection: Finnish Customs Authority (Regional <strong>of</strong>fices)<br />

Sweden � Swedish Environment Agency<br />

Hungary � The Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment and Water<br />

� Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment Revenue Collection<br />

Slovakia<br />

� District Environmental Office<br />

� Slovak Environmental Inspectorate<br />

Typically, it is the Finance Ministry or <strong>Department</strong> which has the power to set the<br />

rates for levies. They may do so in consultation with the Environment Ministry or<br />

<strong>Department</strong>. Responsibility for collection tends to fall with Customs authorities, <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

because these are imbued with powers <strong>of</strong> inspection and <strong>of</strong> entry onto premises,<br />

which allow them to check that levies are being accounted for in the correct manner.<br />

52.3.2 Bans<br />

Usually bans are overseen by the regulatory body for waste management or pollution<br />

prevention and control.<br />

952 Edie (2006) Landfill Tax celebrates a decade <strong>of</strong> environmental support, Accessed on 29 th October<br />

2008, http://www.edie.net/news/news_story.asp?id=12180&channel=0


52.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

Information used within this review draws heavily from the following sources:<br />

763<br />

� Eunomia’s Household waste prevention policy side research programme report<br />

for Defra qualitatively describes the effects <strong>of</strong> the English landfill tax and<br />

Dutch tax and ban. It draws on prior research and comments critically on the<br />

effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the policies to date. Eunomia, The Environment Council, Öko-<br />

Institut, TNO, Atlantic Consulting (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Side Research Programme, Final Report for Defra.<br />

� Ecotec’s study on taxation and charges in Europe includes an in depth review<br />

<strong>of</strong> landfill taxes in England, France and Austria. It includes sections on Tax<br />

Design, Process Development, Organisation Roles, Intentionality <strong>of</strong> the Tax,<br />

Effectiveness, Equity and Distribution, Effect on Producers / Consumers /<br />

Trade / Employment, Internal Market, Competition / Revenue Issues, and<br />

Costs. However, some significant changes have now occurs since the report<br />

was published. Ecotec (2001), Study on the Economic and Environmental<br />

Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes & Charges in the EU.<br />

� The Dutch Environmental Ministry produced a report in 2005 with an ex post<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> the waste tax and ban. Bartelings, H., P. van Beukering, O.<br />

Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk (2005)<br />

Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by<br />

Ministerie von VROM, November 24, 2005.<br />

� European Environment Agency (2005) Market-based instruments for<br />

environmental policy in Europe, EEA Technical report No 8/2005,<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/technical_report_2005_8/en/EEA_technical_re<br />

port_8_2005.pdf<br />

� European Environment Agency (2007) The road from landfilling to recycling:<br />

common destination, different routes,<br />

http://reports.eea.europa.eu/brochure_2007_4<br />

� German case study compiled by the Öko-Institut<br />

� Flemish case study (Flanders Region) compiled by Arcadis<br />

52.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The consequences <strong>of</strong> taxes and bans are difficult to separate out from the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

other instruments in place at the same time. As stated previously, a ban on landfill<br />

does not dictate where the material which can no longer be landfilled will be sent.<br />

Other policies, and market conditions, will dictate how this material is managed.<br />

Where levies are concerned, in principle, it would be possible to structure levies so as<br />

to ‘rig’ the waste management market and make specific options more desirable than<br />

others. To some degree, this is reflected in the structure <strong>of</strong> levies. However, in<br />

practice, most countries use a range <strong>of</strong> complementary instruments to influence the<br />

relative desirability <strong>of</strong> competing options. Consequently, whilst levies make specific<br />

options less desirable, other policies will influence how materials subject to a levy are<br />

dealt with.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Another feature <strong>of</strong> levies is that they generate revenue. Many <strong>of</strong> the countries which<br />

deploy levies do so with the intention <strong>of</strong> using some or all <strong>of</strong> the revenue for specific<br />

purposes related to waste management (or other environmental purposes).<br />

The environmental impact <strong>of</strong> levies and bans, therefore, depends upon both:<br />

764<br />

a) the extent to which the structure <strong>of</strong> levies, or the ban, or both, makes the<br />

activities targeted by the levy and/or the ban less desirable;<br />

b) the way in which other policies affect the desirability <strong>of</strong> alternative<br />

management routes (i.e., those not subject to levies and bans); and<br />

c) where levies are concerned, the effects <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> levy revenue in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental improvement.<br />

Regarding a) and b), own-price and cross-price effects are important. Other things<br />

being equal, a levy would be expected to have consequences which relate to the size<br />

<strong>of</strong> the levy. A ban effectively acts like a levy set at infinity for the treatment subject to<br />

the ban. The own- and cross-price effects will be different for different materials and<br />

for different waste streams, the reason being that the range <strong>of</strong> alternatives, as well as<br />

the costs there<strong>of</strong>, vary by material and stream.<br />

The basic premise is that as landfill prices rise, less waste will be disposed to landfill<br />

and more will be minimised (probably very little in the case <strong>of</strong> municipal waste), reused<br />

and sent to alternative treatments.<br />

The degree to which this occurs relates to the alternatives available and their price<br />

relative to that <strong>of</strong> landfill. Important here is the cross-price elasticity <strong>of</strong> demand. This<br />

shows how sensitive recycling or mechanical biological treatments (MBT), for<br />

example, are to changes in landfill tax. Where technologies are widely available and<br />

where they are competitive in cost, the response can be expected to be considerable.<br />

Similarly, where the opposite is true, the shift away from landfill will be more limited.<br />

When the cost <strong>of</strong> disposal increases above the cost <strong>of</strong> treatment via an alternative<br />

method, this price, know as the substitution price, will determine the marginal waste<br />

management route, as any rational agent will pursue the most cost effective option<br />

(as long as the risks aren’t to great) unless, for example, they are restricted by lengthy<br />

municipal contracts.<br />

Some studies that have attempted to measure the demand for waste disposal<br />

services in general (rather than specifically demand for landfill), conclude that the<br />

demand for municipal services is inelastic. 953 This implies that a large increase in the<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> the service would be needed to see any significant change in the quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

waste sent for disposal. However, studies also indicate that householder’s attitudes<br />

and the implementation <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use charging mechanisms strongly affect the<br />

outcome, implying that the cross-price elasticities <strong>of</strong> demand for waste disposal<br />

services can be relatively elastic. It is not so clear, however, whether changes in<br />

953 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005<br />

29/09/09


disposal costs necessarily would lead to changes in marginal rates being charged for<br />

disposal. Hence, the interaction between pay-by-use and waste taxes cannot be<br />

assumed to be always predictable.<br />

52.5.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention<br />

The environmental benefits from any waste prevention effects would be expected to<br />

include:<br />

765<br />

� reductions in greenhouse gases and aquatic and soil toxicity effects<br />

associated with less material managed in landfill;<br />

� reductions in energy consumption associated with a lower demand for goods;<br />

and<br />

� less hazardous material in the waste stream.<br />

52.5.2 Reduction in <strong>Waste</strong> Generated?<br />

As might be expected for policies developed principally to discourage disposal, the<br />

evidence presented suggests there is minimal effect on waste prevention from these<br />

policies on their own, and that any preventative effect ought, probably, to be<br />

attributed to the combination <strong>of</strong> policies at work in a specific country, and the general<br />

attitude to waste management <strong>of</strong> the population.<br />

In 2004, almost a decade after the Dutch landfill ban had been implemented, VROM<br />

(2004) stated that: 954<br />

‘A weak point in current waste management is that there is still insufficient<br />

grip on the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste produced, particularly consumer waste, which is<br />

still increasing. The situation is being exacerbated as these are also the waste<br />

streams for which the level <strong>of</strong> recovery is lagging behind the targets. A great<br />

deal <strong>of</strong> combustible and recoverable waste is consequently still being<br />

disposed <strong>of</strong> in landfills because, when planning incineration capacity, it had<br />

been assumed that the waste supply would be smaller and the degree <strong>of</strong><br />

separate collection higher.’<br />

Another study noted, regarding the Dutch ban: 955<br />

the effect on prevention is very indirect and very difficult to measure. One has<br />

to see it as a measure that raises prices in the waste management systems,<br />

and that hence, where there is a system for producer responsibility, indirectly<br />

some incentive is created for re-design <strong>of</strong> products in such a way that less<br />

waste is created.<br />

954 VROM (2004) The National <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan, Ministry <strong>of</strong> Housing, Planning and the<br />

Environment, The Hague.<br />

955 Eunomia et al (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report<br />

for Defra.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


766<br />

29/09/09<br />

Probably, there is some interaction also with the implementation <strong>of</strong> DifTar<br />

schemes. If DifTar schemes had been introduced against the backdrop <strong>of</strong><br />

lower costs for residual waste treatment, the structure <strong>of</strong> charges might have<br />

been more difficult for Councils to justify, and the additional costs <strong>of</strong><br />

introducing the system would have been higher (making them more<br />

problematic to justify in the political sphere).<br />

This actually highlights two points:<br />

� The (probably) weak effect in terms <strong>of</strong> waste prevention, associated with the<br />

ban; and<br />

� The difficulties in providing sufficient capacity for treatment <strong>of</strong> specific waste<br />

streams in the context <strong>of</strong> an outright ban, especially in cases such as the<br />

Netherlands, where restrictions on exports for incineration, even where<br />

classified as recovery, are tight.<br />

In respect <strong>of</strong> the first point, this in itself is not evidence <strong>of</strong> a lack <strong>of</strong> any effect <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

prevention. Yet further consideration suggests that the ban probably cannot claim to<br />

have effects which are stronger than the tax for the simple reason that one <strong>of</strong> the key<br />

objectives <strong>of</strong> the ban was to shift waste from landfill to incineration, and the design <strong>of</strong><br />

the tax was, from 2000, used to make incineration less expensive from landfill. One<br />

could argue that the tax itself might have had an effect, in conjunction with the ban.<br />

Yet a report for the Dutch Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment on the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> landfill<br />

taxation concluded that ‘The implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax does not seem to have a<br />

direct effect on the level <strong>of</strong> household waste’. 956 Evidence is less clear in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

non-household waste.<br />

A report by Mazzanti and Zoboli on the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> polices on waste prevention,<br />

waste disposal and landfill analysed waste arisings and economic data, produced by<br />

the EU 25 from 1995 to 2004, used multi-variant analysis to attempt to find any<br />

decoupling <strong>of</strong> waste and GDP growth at the European level. 957 Importantly one <strong>of</strong> its<br />

conclusions is that ‘no landfill or other policy effects seem to provide backward<br />

incentives to waste prevention’. The conclusions also indicate that ‘at all levels other<br />

socio-economic factors were impacting on waste trends; highlighting the importance<br />

<strong>of</strong> societies’ attitudes in waste management.’<br />

The Swedish waste management report from 2008 indicates that in Sweden, despite<br />

the introduction <strong>of</strong> landfill taxation and a ban in 2000 and 2002, respectively, from<br />

2003 to 2007, the quantity <strong>of</strong> municipal waste has increased from 466.4 kg/person<br />

to 513.7 kg/person. 958 Furthermore, as Figure 52-4 shows, there has been no<br />

956 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005<br />

957 M. Mazzanti and R. Zoboli (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> prevention, waste disposal and landfill policies<br />

effectiveness: A quantitative analysis on delinking at European level, Report for Societa Italiana di<br />

economia pubblica, http://www-1.unipv.it/websiep/wp/200720.pdf<br />

958 Avfall Sverige (2008) Swedish <strong>Waste</strong> Mangement, Accessed on 23 rd October 2008<br />

http://www.avfallsverige.se/se/netset/files3/web/P01.m4n?download=true&id=2371_94867351


discernible change in the trend in waste arisings before and after the tax and ban<br />

combination. This suggests minimal effects on the part <strong>of</strong> the combination <strong>of</strong> the tax<br />

and the ban in terms <strong>of</strong> municipal waste prevention. There is a weaker basis for<br />

understanding the effects on industrial wastes.<br />

Figure 52-4: Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Generated in Sweden<br />

kg per capita<br />

767<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

0<br />

1996<br />

Source: Eurostat<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

2002<br />

Year<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

2004<br />

2006<br />

Municipal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Generated - kg per<br />

capita<br />

Since 2000, in the Flanders Region <strong>of</strong> Belgium there has been a ban on the landfilling<br />

<strong>of</strong> untreated municipal waste. Subsequently, the amount <strong>of</strong> household waste in<br />

Flanders has ceased increasing. In 2002, it decreased by 0.2% and in 2003 by 3.4%.<br />

Major factors behind these figures are likely to have been the widespread availability<br />

<strong>of</strong> separate collection facilities and the application in almost all Flemish<br />

municipalities <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use charges. 959 To the extent that pay by use may have had<br />

some impact, this may prove to be a one-<strong>of</strong>f impact. Furthermore, the apparent<br />

change in trend could also be attributed to the positive attitudes to waste<br />

management <strong>of</strong> the population.<br />

Bans would be expected to have the strongest influence in those situations where the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling are much lower than the costs <strong>of</strong> many <strong>of</strong> the alternatives which<br />

might be expected to be deployed to deal with wastes subject to a ban. Germany<br />

maybe one such case and Wallonia may be another.<br />

Intriguingly, some anecdotal evidence may lend some support to this view. For<br />

example, a recent study for OVAM indicated that Wallonia has the lowest residual<br />

959 A. Sanders, L. Putseys and E. Van Der Putten (2004) Beheer van afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen. Chapter 2.17. In<br />

Milieurapport Vlaanderen (MIRA), www.milieurapport.be


waste per inhabitant <strong>of</strong> any <strong>of</strong> the regions examined in the study (Flanders, Wallonia,<br />

Nord Pas-de-calais, Nordrhein Westfalen, Brussels Region and the Netherlands). 960<br />

In addition, our own work in Germany examining pay-by-use schemes suggests that<br />

the cost differential between landfill and incineration / other pre-treatment<br />

anticipated by some local authorities in the years prior to the restriction on landfilling<br />

being enforced led to them reconfiguring the charging schemes they used to<br />

incentivise households to increase recycling and prevent waste. 961 Figure 52-5 also<br />

demonstrates a quite significant drop <strong>of</strong>f in municipal waste, though the picture is far<br />

less clear in respect <strong>of</strong> production and commercial waste (equivalent to commercial<br />

and industrial waste in the UK). This has shown a more volatile trend. It should be<br />

noted that in the Figure, the main change in total waste quantities comes through<br />

reductions in construction and demolition waste landfilled, this being affected by<br />

different drivers to the landfill ban.<br />

Figure 52-5: Evolution in <strong>Waste</strong> Arisings in Germany, 2000-2006<br />

960 OVAM (2007) Market Study <strong>of</strong> the Final Treatment <strong>of</strong> Residual Household <strong>Waste</strong> and Industrial<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Similar to Household <strong>Waste</strong> in Flanders and Neighbouring Regions: a Summary Report, August<br />

2007.<br />

961 See the case <strong>of</strong> Landkreis Schweinfurt in D. Hogg (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection<br />

Charges ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD and Eunomia (2003) To Charge or Not to<br />

Charge? Final report to IWM (EB).<br />

768<br />

29/09/09


A report on Finnish waste management suggests that waste taxation is considered<br />

not to have contributed much to waste prevention. 962 Figure 52-6 shows that<br />

changes in tax rates have had little effect on waste quantities, with the possible<br />

exception <strong>of</strong> the rise which took place in 2000. However, other rises do not seem to<br />

have had a significant impact.<br />

Figure 52-6: <strong>Waste</strong> Quantities and Tax Rates in Finland<br />

Source: Christian Fischer (2008) The Use <strong>of</strong> Landfill and Incineration <strong>Waste</strong> Taxes in<br />

Selected EU Countries, Presentation to EU-Asia Sustainable <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Cycle, CBPIII, 17 April 2008.<br />

A report for the Dutch Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment on the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> landfill<br />

taxation concluded that ‘The implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax does not seem to have a<br />

direct effect on the level <strong>of</strong> household waste’. 963<br />

Since 2000, in the Flanders Region <strong>of</strong> Belgium there has been a ban on the landfilling<br />

<strong>of</strong> untreated municipal waste. Subsequently, the amount <strong>of</strong> household waste in<br />

Flanders has ceased increasing. In 2002, it decreased by 0.2% and in 2003 by 3.4%.<br />

Major factors behind these figures are the widespread availability <strong>of</strong> separate<br />

962 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Finland <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Finland<br />

963 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.<br />

769<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


collection facilities and the application in almost all Flemish municipalities <strong>of</strong> pay-byuse<br />

charges. 964 To the extent that pay by use may have had some impact, this may<br />

prove to be a one-<strong>of</strong>f impact. Furthermore, the apparent change in trend could also<br />

be attributed to the positive attitudes to waste management <strong>of</strong> the population.<br />

These results could also be confirmed by the situation in Luxembourg which has seen<br />

an overall stabilisation <strong>of</strong> household waste generated despite no taxes or bans having<br />

been implemented. 965966<br />

In the UK, it is difficult to be clear whether the landfill tax, which has escalated<br />

significantly in recent years, has had a strong impact upon waste prevention. In the<br />

household sector, it seems reasonable to argue that the tax will have had little or no<br />

impact upon household waste growth for the simple reason that there is no means <strong>of</strong><br />

conveying, to the householder, the changing cost <strong>of</strong> disposal other than through a flat<br />

rate increase in the Council Tax levied locally. Notwithstanding this, municipal waste<br />

growth rates have been in decline since 2000, though much <strong>of</strong> this may be<br />

attributable to the effect <strong>of</strong> the LAS, which has generated an incentive for local<br />

authorities to minimise the quantity <strong>of</strong> non-household municipal waste which they<br />

collect. 967<br />

The situation for non-household waste from commerce and industry is almost<br />

certainly very different, only partly because revenues from the tax have been recycled<br />

into schemes designed to foster increased resource efficiency (with prevention and<br />

re-use being prominent in these). However, the quality <strong>of</strong> the available data does not<br />

inspire one to suggest that a basis for any trend analysis exists, let alone, that the<br />

basis for discerning a clear change in trend due to the tax is reliable. Rather, the<br />

evidence is more anecdotal, and where surveys <strong>of</strong> commercial and industrial waste<br />

have been carried out, quite suggestive. In addition, a report by ECOTEC following the<br />

tax’s introduction suggested that, on the basis <strong>of</strong> a survey, the tax had been a key<br />

factor leading some businesses to reappraise their waste management behaviour. In<br />

964 A. Sanders, l. Putseys and E. Van Der Putten (2004) Beheer van afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen. Chapter 2.17. In<br />

Milieurapport Vlaanderen (MIRA), www.milieurapport.be<br />

965 Luxembourg Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment (2006) <strong>Waste</strong> Statistics Website, Accessed on 16 th<br />

October 2008, http://www.statistiques.public.lu/stat/TableViewer/tableView.aspx?ReportId=1036<br />

966 EIONET: European Topic Centre on Resource and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (2007) Luxembourg <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Factsheet, Accessed 16 th October 2008,<br />

http://waste.eionet.europa.eu/facts/factsheets_waste/Luxembourg<br />

967 It is important to recognise that in the UK, and indeed, several other EU countries, municipal waste<br />

is defined as, effectively, an administrative category. The quantity <strong>of</strong> waste regarded as ‘municipal’<br />

depends upon whether the waste is collected by, or on behalf <strong>of</strong>, the local authority. Decisions by local<br />

authorities to collect, or not collect, commercial waste will influence the quantity <strong>of</strong> municipal waste<br />

reported. This – the difference in the way the definition <strong>of</strong> ‘municipal waste’ is applied - is a key reason<br />

why a) EU statistics regarding municipal waste are essentially non-comparable, and b) attempts at<br />

cross-country analysis <strong>of</strong> the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> policy instruments are likely to be thwarted unless<br />

account is taken <strong>of</strong> the way instruments and definitions are applied in different countries (and such<br />

studies are rare, if not, completely absent).<br />

770<br />

29/09/09


some cases, notably in the foundry sector, this led to waste prevention effects, with<br />

commensurate savings to the businesses concerned. 968<br />

52.5.3 Hazardousness <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> reducing the hazardousness <strong>of</strong> waste, beyond the regulatory measures in<br />

the Landfill Directive, levies and bans have not been widely used to influence the<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> hazardous waste. One reason for this is that it is generally considered<br />

‘potentially problematic’ to make treatment / disposal <strong>of</strong> hazardous waste much<br />

more expensive than it already is because <strong>of</strong> the potential dangers associated with<br />

illegal disposal <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials.<br />

Some countries have bucked this trend and have applied increased levels <strong>of</strong> taxation<br />

for hazardous materials, such as in Slovakia. In the Czech Republic there is a ‘risk’<br />

component <strong>of</strong> the tax to cover hazardous materials. As a general principle, and as<br />

mentioned in Section 52.11, high levels <strong>of</strong> taxation and unmanageable bans are to<br />

be avoided to limit illegal dumping <strong>of</strong> environmentally damaging substances. Indeed,<br />

there are good reasons to argue that hazardous materials ought not to be subject to<br />

punitive measures so as to ensure that improper disposal <strong>of</strong> hazardous materials<br />

does not become problematic.<br />

In summary, the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste prevented and thus the waste prevention related<br />

environmental benefits from the implementation <strong>of</strong> waste treatment taxes and bans<br />

are likely to have been minimal, if there are in fact any at all. Benefits from the<br />

reduction <strong>of</strong> materials which are hazardous in the context <strong>of</strong> landfilling may have<br />

arisen following banning <strong>of</strong> such wastes from landfill.<br />

52.5.4 Recycling<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the environmental benefits associated with recycling relate, as with waste<br />

prevention, to avoidance <strong>of</strong> landfilling, but there will also be additional savings from<br />

avoiding virgin material use, and the associated embodied energy achieved through<br />

material recovery.<br />

Recycling rates in most <strong>of</strong> the countries considered in this report have been<br />

increasing (though in some, such as Denmark, this is barely discernable any more).<br />

As with waste prevention, however, there is relatively little documented evidence to<br />

demonstrate that the introduction <strong>of</strong> a tax or a ban on its own correlates strongly to<br />

any increase in recycling.<br />

In the UK, one study suggested that when it was first introduced, the tax led to several<br />

companies reviewing their waste management operations, and changing<br />

arrangements to increase recycling <strong>of</strong> waste. 969<br />

968 See ECOTEC (1997), Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Tax in the UK: Barriers to Increased Effectiveness<br />

and Options for the Future, A Final Report for Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth, Birmingham: ECOTEC; D. Hogg<br />

(1999), ‘The Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the UK Landfill Tax - Early Indications’, in Sterner, Thomas (ed) (1999),<br />

Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> Market-based <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments, Cheltenham and :Edward Elgar<br />

771<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Where household waste is concerned, recycling rates have tended to be driven more<br />

by recycling targets and, more recently, by the LASs. The situation is almost certainly<br />

very different where commercial and industrial wastes are concerned, though the<br />

data is not <strong>of</strong> sufficient quality to confirm this. Particularly as the tax has increased<br />

more recently, growing emphasis has been placed upon recycling <strong>of</strong> commercial and<br />

industrial waste, and the diversity <strong>of</strong> collection schemes reflects this.<br />

In Denmark it was reported that the overall recycling rate <strong>of</strong> 61% <strong>of</strong> all waste in 1996<br />

was the result <strong>of</strong> a comprehensive waste reduction policy with several elements,<br />

including the waste tax. 970 Furthermore, the establishment <strong>of</strong> new recycling facilities,<br />

especially for construction and demolition waste (see Section 52.12), and garden<br />

waste was considered to have played a prominent role.<br />

It is also interesting to note that the year in which the ban was introduced, 1997, was<br />

the same year in which the waste tax was significantly increased. Studies by CESAM<br />

suggest the tax, not the ban, has influenced changes in waste quantities, but that<br />

these effects have been at best limited outside the sphere <strong>of</strong> construction and<br />

demolition waste. 971 One commentator notes: 972<br />

772<br />

29/09/09<br />

As a conclusion it could be said, that while taxes are very effective in changing<br />

the way waste is managed, it seems as if they have no or very little effect on<br />

the total amount <strong>of</strong> waste generated. Denmark has not succeeded in delinking<br />

the growth in waste from the growth in GDP.<br />

In relation to non-landfill technologies, a Dutch report concludes that little technical<br />

change has been seen in the Netherlands in terms <strong>of</strong> new incinerators, but the use <strong>of</strong><br />

SRF abroad has increased. 973 Additionally, any link between the landfill ban and the<br />

tax, and recycling infrastructure was described as ‘ambiguous’.<br />

In Germany, where no tax is in place, and where (as discussed above) the differential<br />

between the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling and <strong>of</strong>, for example, incineration or MBT, is large,<br />

there may have been more <strong>of</strong> an incentive effect. This might be partly an explanation<br />

for the continuing increase in German recycling rates even some time after the<br />

general frameworks for waste management were well established, and even in the<br />

969 ECOTEC and Cambridge Econometrics (1997), Employment and Sustainability: The UK Landfill Tax,<br />

Final Report for the European Foundation for the Improvement <strong>of</strong> Living and Working Conditions,<br />

Dublin: EFILWC.<br />

970 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005<br />

971 Miljøstyrelsen, Working report no. 18 (1999) and Miljøstyrelsen, Working report no. 23 (1999).<br />

972 Suzanne Arup Veltzé (2003) Taxes on <strong>Waste</strong>, a Steering Instrument – Experience from Denmark,<br />

Presentation at ISWA Beacon Conference Seminar, 23-24 October 2003, Malmo, Sweden.<br />

973 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.


absence <strong>of</strong> any form <strong>of</strong> waste tax. Figure 52-7 shows the evolution <strong>of</strong> recycling and<br />

composting rates for municipal waste in Germany from 1995 to 2007.<br />

Figure 52-7: Recycling and Composting Rates for Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> in Germany<br />

Rate <strong>of</strong> Material Recovery (%)<br />

773<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

0%<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Year<br />

Recycling and Composting<br />

Recycling<br />

Composting<br />

Source: Eurostat (note the figures for 1996 and 2007 are country estimates, whilst<br />

the figures for 1995 are Eurostat estimates).<br />

In addition, Figure 52-8 shows the rates <strong>of</strong> recovery for key waste fractions in<br />

Germany. Of particular interest is the fairly rapid increase in recovery <strong>of</strong> Production<br />

and Commercial waste (as stated above, equivalent to the UK’s commercial and<br />

industrial waste), which rises from 50% in 2000 to over 80% in 2006. It is not clear to<br />

what extent the recovery reflects and increase in thermal recovery, or an increase in<br />

recycling. This may, however, indicate the more market sensitive nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Production and Commercial waste stream, with the ban’s effect causing a shift <strong>of</strong><br />

material away from disposal and into recovery.


Figure 52-8: Recovery Rates for <strong>Waste</strong> Fractions in Germany<br />

Generally, the absence <strong>of</strong> strong evidence should not be taken as evidence <strong>of</strong> the<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> an effect. Most countries which deploy landfill taxes and bans, however,<br />

also deploy an armoury <strong>of</strong> other policy instruments. Taxes and bans tend to support<br />

these policies, and assist in moving waste up the hierarchy, but the degree to which<br />

they, and not other policies, are responsible is difficult to discern.<br />

52.5.5 Reduction in Landfilling<br />

There are generally benefits associated with reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste disposed<br />

<strong>of</strong> in landfills, though these vary with the nature <strong>of</strong> the material, and with the change<br />

in the management method. For example, when plastics are switched from landfill to<br />

incineration, the net impact in terms <strong>of</strong> climate change is, under most reasonable<br />

assumptions, strongly negative.<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> policies discussed in this Section relate to mechanisms for<br />

discouraging disposal <strong>of</strong> waste in landfill, and this is the focus <strong>of</strong> the discussion.<br />

However, some mention <strong>of</strong> the environmental impacts from incineration can be found<br />

below in Section 52.5.6.<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> landfill bans indicated in this report relate to wastes <strong>of</strong> a hazardous<br />

nature (see Section 52.5.1), and bans on combustible or biodegradable wastes. In<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> combustible waste, the driver for the implementation <strong>of</strong> regulatory ban has<br />

historically come from those countries with high levels <strong>of</strong> incineration wanting to<br />

control the flow <strong>of</strong> waste into their treatment plants, for example, in Demark, The<br />

774<br />

29/09/09


Netherlands and Sweden. One might argue, therefore, that the principle switch<br />

achieved by this is one from landfill to incineration.<br />

The key driver for the implementation <strong>of</strong> regulatory bans on biowaste comes from the<br />

desire to reduce problems associated with methane generation at landfills, or (which<br />

amounts to much the same thing) to meet landfill directive targets. Note that no<br />

equivalent driver has been found in any state outside <strong>of</strong> Europe. The European<br />

countries that have landfill bans in place that specifically target biodegradable waste,<br />

are Austria, Finland, Germany, Belgium, France, Sweden, Czech Republic, and<br />

Slovenia. The benefit from eliminating such materials from landfill may be significant<br />

considering the propensity <strong>of</strong> biodegradable wastes to generate methane in the<br />

anaerobic conditions that occur in landfills.<br />

The effectiveness <strong>of</strong> a landfill ban can relate to the notice given by the relevant<br />

government before the implementation <strong>of</strong> the ban. Essentially, if not enough time is<br />

given infrastructure does not have time to develop and infringements are likely to<br />

occur. This is discussed further in the Section 52.12. Of course, where a lead time is<br />

used, it does make any assessment <strong>of</strong> the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> a ban more difficult to<br />

assess.<br />

The level <strong>of</strong> detailed data that could be used to perform a thorough ex-post evaluation<br />

<strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> landfill tax mechanisms is simply not available. We have therefore<br />

pulled together sparse information from relevant reports and highlighted some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

important issues.<br />

To determine what environmental benefits are associated with a landfill tax, one<br />

study sought to understand whether there is a relationship between the level <strong>of</strong> the<br />

tax and the proportion <strong>of</strong> waste landfilled in that country. Figure 52-9 shows that, at a<br />

glance, no relationship exists between landfill tax levels and municipal waste<br />

landfilled. However, the combination <strong>of</strong> waste policies in each <strong>of</strong> the countries, and<br />

specific intentions <strong>of</strong> the landfill tax, are different, making such a univariate analysis<br />

almost useless. For example, one <strong>of</strong> the clear outliers is Germany (DE), with a low<br />

level <strong>of</strong> municipal waste landfilled but no landfill tax. In Germany the Ordinance on<br />

Landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste significantly restricts landfilling, and has had a significant effect in<br />

reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste landfilled. Equally, to take the view that the tax is<br />

responsible for the low levels <strong>of</strong> landfilling in Netherlands and Denmark would be to<br />

miss the influence <strong>of</strong> the landfill bans in those countries.<br />

775<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 52-9: Correlation between Landfill Tax and <strong>Waste</strong> Landfilled<br />

Source: Bartelings, H., P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A.<br />

Wagtendonk (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie<br />

von VROM, November 24, 2005.<br />

France (FR) also looks like the tax has had a pronounced effect relative to other EU<br />

countries. However, the level indicated in this chart only relates to the level <strong>of</strong> tax that<br />

is chargeable for waste deposited in legal landfill sites. There has historically been a<br />

large quantity <strong>of</strong> waste deposited in unregistered sites in France, and this waste is<br />

subject to a higher level <strong>of</strong> landfill tax (around 36 €). This and the regulatory ban on a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> waste streams, has had the effect <strong>of</strong> reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> municipal<br />

waste to a lower level than in countries with a higher rate for licensed landfills e.g. the<br />

UK.<br />

The Netherlands (NL) has, what looks like, an over inflated landfill tax compared to<br />

other EU countries whereby similar levels <strong>of</strong> municipal waste landfilled can be<br />

achieved through lower rates. This is most certainly the case, but there has been a<br />

relatively unique case in Dutch waste management. In the late 1980s the Dutch were<br />

rebuilding their incineration capacity with much higher pollution control mechanisms<br />

following a dioxin emissions scandal. Fiscal and regulatory measures were needed to<br />

ensure that incineration capacity would be used, and hence, that the high investment<br />

cost would not be wasted. A landfill ban on all combustible waste was implemented<br />

and the landfill tax was escalated sharply between 1995 and 2003. A Dutch study<br />

indicates that in the same period: 974<br />

974 MNP (2005), Milieubalans 2005, Milieu- en Natuurplanbureau, Bilthoven.<br />

776<br />

29/09/09


777<br />

‘the amount <strong>of</strong> landfilled waste decreased by around two thirds from 8.215<br />

ktonne to 2.753 ktonne. During the same period, the amount <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

incinerated increased by around 75% from 4.695 ktonne to 8.218 ktonne.’<br />

The sharp rise in landfill tax increased the cost <strong>of</strong> disposal to a point where landfill<br />

gate fees exceeded the gate fee for incinerators. Therefore the lower cost <strong>of</strong><br />

managing waste by incineration meant that incineration substituted landfilling, where<br />

possible, and thus allowed for a more efficient allocation <strong>of</strong> resources.<br />

UK Experience<br />

Figure 52-10 shows how the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste landfilled has changed over time in the<br />

UK. The most relevant quantity for the purposes <strong>of</strong> this study is the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

landfilled in the standard rate category. This remained fairly stable from 1997/98 to<br />

2002/03, but has fallen since then. The fall has been <strong>of</strong> the order 11 million tonnes.<br />

We estimate that changes in the management <strong>of</strong> municipal waste accounts for<br />

around 5 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> this fall.<br />

Figure 52-10: Quantities <strong>of</strong> Landfilled <strong>Waste</strong> in the UK<br />

Tonnes Landfilled ('000 tonnes)<br />

120,000<br />

100,000<br />

80,000<br />

60,000<br />

40,000<br />

20,000<br />

0<br />

1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08<br />

Source: based on data from HMRC<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

3% 3% per per annum annum annum nominal nominal increase,<br />

increase,<br />

approx approx 0% 0% in in real real terms<br />

terms<br />

£1 £1 per per tonne tonne per per per annum annum escalator escalator £3 £3 per tonne per annum annum annum escalator<br />

escalator<br />

Financial Year<br />

8% 8% per per per annum annum nominal nominal increase, increase,<br />

increase,<br />

approx approx 5% 5% in in in real real terms<br />

terms<br />

Exempt<br />

Lower rate<br />

Standard rate<br />

The remaining drop is likely to be due either to a decline in commercial and industrial<br />

waste arisings, or to waste moving into other non-landfill routes. This drop would be<br />

against the backdrop <strong>of</strong> our estimate <strong>of</strong> UK commercial and industrial waste landfilled<br />

<strong>of</strong> the order 34 million tonnes across the UK early in the decade.<br />

The commercial and industrial waste market is, in principle, more dynamic than the<br />

municipal one (owing to the more ‘naked’ nature <strong>of</strong> the competition), yet at the same<br />

time, this competition can have the effect <strong>of</strong> slowing down development <strong>of</strong><br />

infrastructure and services (because <strong>of</strong> the increased risk associated with ensuring<br />

sufficient supply into the investment).


The reason for this is that the competition for waste services reduces the security<br />

which any developer <strong>of</strong> more capital intense facilities might have that waste will come<br />

into the facility in the quantity and manner desired. In essence, investments are more<br />

risky than they are in the case – as with municipal waste – where flows <strong>of</strong> waste can<br />

be more or less guaranteed under long-term contracts.<br />

In order for developers to have some certainty that waste will flow into specific<br />

facilities, the economic conditions must be right. The lack <strong>of</strong> increase (in real terms)<br />

in landfill costs implied by the landfill tax in the period to 2003-04 can partly explain<br />

what would appear – at least at the UK level - to be a lack <strong>of</strong> any very strong shift<br />

from landfill to other treatments as a result <strong>of</strong> the tax. This may have changed since<br />

2002-03 (with the increase in landfill tax escalator), but it is far more likely that<br />

greater changes will come as the escalator increases the tax to £72 per tonne by<br />

2013.<br />

Pre-treatment requirements may also be encouraging segregation <strong>of</strong> wastes by<br />

companies which have not hitherto been engaged in any such activity, although the<br />

UK pre-treatment requirements demand minimal change on the part <strong>of</strong> most waste<br />

producers.<br />

With respect to household waste, the landfill tax has been far less influential in<br />

driving waste away from landfill. The LASs have been more important in recent years.<br />

Finland<br />

The Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment assessed the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> waste tax in Finland in<br />

a report published in 2005, which indicates that waste taxation has helped to reduce<br />

the amounts <strong>of</strong> waste ending up in public landfills in spite <strong>of</strong> increasing consumption.<br />

Reductions were particularly significant for construction, commercial and industrial<br />

wastes. Taxation controls have been less effective in terms <strong>of</strong> limiting household<br />

waste.<br />

Sweden<br />

A report by the Swedish Environmental Protection Agency stated that although the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> waste going to landfill had actually decreased, there was much doubt as to<br />

the quantified effects <strong>of</strong> the landfill tax. 975 This was because the tax was evaluated<br />

when it had only been in place for a short time, there was limited access to the data<br />

that could be used for the evaluation, and waste management policy includes a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> other instruments alongside the landfill tax.<br />

As regards the Swedish incineration tax, a study by Sahlin et al suggested that the<br />

incineration tax would have the largest effect on biological treatment <strong>of</strong> kitchen and<br />

garden waste, which could increase by 9%. 976 The authors stated that the<br />

975 Naturvårdsverket (2003) Ekonomiska styrmedel inom miljöområdet - en sammanställning. Rapport<br />

5333, Naturvårdsverket, Stockholm.<br />

976 J. Sahlin, T. Ekvall, M. Bisaillon and J. Sundberg (2007) Introduction <strong>of</strong> a waste incineration tax:<br />

Effects on the Swedish waste flows, Resources, Conservation and Recycling, Volume 51, Issue 4,<br />

October 2007, pp. 827-846.<br />

778<br />

29/09/09


consequences <strong>of</strong> an incineration tax depend upon: (a) the level <strong>of</strong> the tax, (b) whether<br />

the tax is based on an assumed average Swedish fossil carbon content or on the<br />

measured carbon content in each incineration plant, (c) institutional factors such as<br />

the cooperation between waste incinerators, and (d) technological factors such as the<br />

availability <strong>of</strong> central sorting <strong>of</strong> waste or techniques for measurement <strong>of</strong> fossil carbon<br />

in exhaust gases, etc. Information turns out to be a key factor in transferring the<br />

governing force <strong>of</strong> the tax to the households as well improving the households’<br />

attitudes towards material recycling.<br />

Others<br />

Table 52-6 below shows the reported effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the landfill tax in some more <strong>of</strong><br />

the Member States according to a Dutch study.<br />

As one can see from the tax effectiveness evaluation summaries presented in the<br />

Dutch report there is no strong evidence to show that the landfill tax or ban on its own<br />

has a great impact on the change in municipal waste landfilled over time, and thus in<br />

associated environmental benefit. What is clear is that a tax can be used effectively in<br />

combination with a range <strong>of</strong> other regulatory measures, to divert waste from landfill.<br />

Where this waste will be diverted to will be related to prices for the alternative<br />

management routes and other institutional factors, historical trends in waste<br />

management (Denmark – incineration, Belgium - recycling), technical change<br />

following pollution scandals (The Netherlands, Austria), or a means to assist in<br />

securing supply <strong>of</strong> waste for incinerators mainly in countries where district heat<br />

networks were existing (Denmark, The Netherlands, Germany, Finland, Sweden).<br />

Summary<br />

To summarise, waste taxes or bans can be used by governments, as part <strong>of</strong> a<br />

package <strong>of</strong> measures, to help divert municipal waste from landfill and direct it to<br />

alternative residual treatments as required (the rate <strong>of</strong> tax levied on each type <strong>of</strong><br />

treatment will determine how waste disposal authorities will act – based on cost<br />

effectiveness only – and hence what treatment is favoured). Or, if a greater level <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste recycling is the favoured alternative to disposal in landfill (or via<br />

other residual management processes), because it is the householders making the<br />

decision as to whether the waste will be recycled, they must feel the price signal from<br />

a tax though some differentiated unit-based pricing scheme. Such systems are in<br />

accordance with the ‘polluter pays principle’ and can contribute to an efficient<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> resources, because they imply a non-zero marginal cost <strong>of</strong> waste and<br />

thus stimulate recycling and waste prevention. 977 However, unit-based pricing<br />

systems also have some disadvantages. They sometimes involve high transaction<br />

costs, and tend to stimulate the illegal disposal <strong>of</strong> waste. Relevant to both taxes and<br />

bans (as the success in Belgium has shown), is that widespread and easy to access<br />

recycling collections must be in place to help behavioural change.<br />

977 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.<br />

779<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 52-6: Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Taxes in European Member States<br />

780<br />

Country Country<br />

Country<br />

Denmark High<br />

29/09/09<br />

Landfill Landfill<br />

Landfill<br />

Diversion Diversion<br />

Diversion<br />

Austria Medium<br />

Finland<br />

Belgium –<br />

Flanders<br />

Low /<br />

Medium<br />

High<br />

Tax Tax Tax Effectiveness<br />

Effectiveness<br />

Effectiveness<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> strong incentives to incinerate waste in<br />

Denmark. These are in place because incineration was chosen<br />

as a preferential method for generating energy in comparison<br />

to fossil fuel based processes. A landfill ban on all combustible<br />

materials is in force and price ceilings on the sale <strong>of</strong> heat have<br />

been set so that EfW is more cost effective. It is difficult to say<br />

which factor (including the tax) has had more effect, but it is<br />

clear that the Danish system is unique.<br />

However, this was reported as ‘the result <strong>of</strong> a comprehensive<br />

waste reduction policy with several elements, including the<br />

waste tax’, and that much <strong>of</strong> the reduction had come from<br />

unregulated areas.<br />

The tax has had a clear effect on the level <strong>of</strong> technologies at<br />

landfill sites, but the 30% reduction in municipal waste<br />

between 1989 and 1999, could well have been attributed to<br />

other regulations and an increased awareness <strong>of</strong> recycling and<br />

composting.<br />

The waste disposal policies in Finland are, like in Denmark,<br />

designed to provide a secure supply <strong>of</strong> waste to EfW plants.<br />

Combustible waste must be source separated and is also<br />

banned from landfilling. Up until 2003, when the level <strong>of</strong> the<br />

tax was low (27 €) there was doubt as to the quantifiable effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> it having any bearing on the reduction in waste landfill that<br />

was observed. No evidence was found to show what has<br />

happened since the tax was subsequently increased to (40 €).<br />

It is therefore not possible to clearly state the result <strong>of</strong> the tax<br />

in isolation, but it is likely that the mix <strong>of</strong> policies have diverted<br />

waste from landfilling to recycling and incineration.<br />

The amount <strong>of</strong> waste being disposed <strong>of</strong> in landfills decreased<br />

from 52.6% to 16.3% between 1991 and 2003. The amount <strong>of</strong><br />

waste generated per annum has actually started to decline<br />

since 2003. The complex system <strong>of</strong> differentiated taxes and<br />

bans has been highlighted as being responsible for this<br />

decrease, but that major factors that have contributed to the<br />

diversion <strong>of</strong> waste from landfill (mainly to recycling) are - the<br />

widespread availability <strong>of</strong> separate collection facilities and the<br />

application in almost all Flemish municipalities <strong>of</strong> some kind <strong>of</strong><br />

differentiation in waste collection charges.<br />

Source: Adapted from Bartelings, H., P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander<br />

and A. Wagtendonk (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by<br />

Ministerie von VROM, November 24, 2005


52.5.6 Reduction in Incineration<br />

As shown in Section 52.5.5 above, waste taxes and bans can achieve a certain level<br />

<strong>of</strong> environmental benefit by diverting waste from landfills. However, as also touched<br />

upon, to what process the waste is diverted will also have an impact on the net<br />

environmental benefit from the switch in management methods. Several countries in<br />

Europe have constructed taxes and bans to switch waste from landfilling to<br />

incineration, mainly through bans targeting waste described as ‘combustible’, and<br />

through setting up tax differentials against the backdrop <strong>of</strong> a static situation in<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> recycling.<br />

Switching from a poor performing landfill to an efficient incinerator with extensive flue<br />

gas cleaning equipment installed, is unequivocally going to provide you with greater<br />

environmental benefit than from switching waste from a fully sealed landfill with a<br />

high gas capture rate and subsequent generation <strong>of</strong> energy, to a low performing EfW<br />

plant. The Dutch report on landfill effectiveness performed a cost benefit analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill, incineration and co-incineration. This study took full consideration <strong>of</strong> the<br />

environmental externalities associated with each. It found that incineration had<br />

significantly higher social costs than landfilling.<br />

As Austria successfully managed to do with landfill technology, several countries are<br />

using waste taxes and bans to manage the environmental performance <strong>of</strong> EfW plants,<br />

or in fact, actually discourage their use in favour <strong>of</strong> recycling by levying rates on the<br />

combustion <strong>of</strong> waste. In Sweden, for example, the amount <strong>of</strong> the tax is calculated<br />

based on a model <strong>of</strong> the fossil content <strong>of</strong> material in the waste. 978 Furthermore, the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> tax is dependent on whether facilities produce electricity and, if so, how<br />

efficiently. In Norway there is an emissions based tax that focuses on pollutants such<br />

as CO2, NOx, SOx, particulates and dioxins. The tax was developed to be revenue<br />

neutral and not change the balance <strong>of</strong> residual treatments.<br />

If incineration is compared to recycling, in terms <strong>of</strong> cost effective GHG performance, it<br />

fairs worse in most cases, except when looking specifically at the combustion <strong>of</strong> low<br />

grade wood. 979 If one were to include a whole range <strong>of</strong> environmental factors the true<br />

social cost is likely to be considerably worse for incineration. Thus several countries<br />

include taxation or banning policy mechanisms to discourage the disposal / recovery<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste in EfW plants, and to promote recycling. 980 In Belgium, for example,<br />

incineration is forbidden for:<br />

978 Avfall Sverige (2008) Swedish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>,<br />

http://www.avfallsverige.se/se/netset/files3/web/P01.m4n?download=true&id=2371_94867351<br />

979 Eunomia (2008) Development <strong>of</strong> Marginal Abatement Cost Curves for the UK <strong>Waste</strong> Sector, Final<br />

Report for the Committee on Climate Change, Defra and EA.<br />

980 Historically waste could be ‘disposed’ <strong>of</strong> in incinerators where there was no means to recovery any<br />

energy from the process. Consequently the <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration Directive required that all incinerators<br />

must generate some form <strong>of</strong> energy, be it heat or electricity only, or combined heat and power (CHP).<br />

Hence why incineration is <strong>of</strong>ten referred to as energy from waste (EfW). One <strong>of</strong> the last amendments to<br />

the European <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive stipulated that EfW could be categorised as a recovery<br />

process, rather than a disposal process, but only if the specific facility met certain requirements in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> energy efficiency, hence discouraging the management <strong>of</strong> waste in EfW facilities due to low<br />

781<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


782<br />

� Separately collected waste fit for material recovery or recycling, except some<br />

types <strong>of</strong> biowaste if they have a caloric value <strong>of</strong> above 11.500 kJ/kg and used<br />

for the creation <strong>of</strong> renewable energy;<br />

� Unsorted industrial waste; and<br />

� Unsorted household waste.<br />

Moreover, a tax is levied on any waste where BAT for sorting exists. The tax is<br />

differentiated in relation to the level <strong>of</strong> sorting carried out, thus strongly incentivising<br />

source segregated separation and recycling. Consequently Belgium has one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

highest recycling rates in the world. Additionally, Denmark, Norway, Sweden, and the<br />

Catalonia region <strong>of</strong> Spain, all have some form <strong>of</strong> taxation or banning policy in place.<br />

Considering Denmark’s desire to use EfW to generate heat for its district heating<br />

networks, it seems likely that this tax could just be a revenue raiser for the<br />

government’s budget.<br />

Interestingly, if one refers back to Table 52-1, several <strong>of</strong> the countries with high<br />

recycling rates, but high incineration, have a policy mechanism for discouraging EfW,<br />

and none <strong>of</strong> the countries with high recycling and low incineration do. In fact they all<br />

have relatively low landfill taxes as well. This most probably indicates that taxation <strong>of</strong><br />

residual treatments is an effective means to promote the switching <strong>of</strong> waste between<br />

treatments, but that other policy mechanisms are more effective at promoting<br />

material recovery and recycling.<br />

52.5.7 Commercial and Industrial <strong>Waste</strong>s<br />

The data for commercial and industrial waste is generally less comprehensive than<br />

for municipal wastes, and sometimes non-existent. Thus there has been very little<br />

reference to C&I wastes in any <strong>of</strong> the evaluation studies queried. So this section will<br />

take an overview <strong>of</strong> what are considered to be the important issues and highlight the<br />

small points from literature where applicable.<br />

C&I businesses have waste collection by private waste collection companies and are<br />

generally charged by weight or volume <strong>of</strong> waste collected. <strong>Waste</strong> collection<br />

companies will pass the price <strong>of</strong> an increase in landfill taxation directly through to<br />

them by increasing, for example, the cost per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste collected. This gives a<br />

direct signal to the business that it must reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> waste that it produces.<br />

Ecotec report that in England:<br />

29/09/09<br />

‘There is some evidence that the landfill tax has had an effect on the disposal<br />

<strong>of</strong> commercial and industrial waste.’<br />

This was relating to a survey <strong>of</strong> firms which suggested that the introduction <strong>of</strong> the<br />

landfill tax stimulated waste minimisation and recycling activities. Such evidence has<br />

been backed up by work undertaken for the Environmental Technology Best Practice<br />

programme, a UK Government initiative that provides free advice to industry on<br />

GHG performance vis-à-vis recycling, or because <strong>of</strong> it’s net social cost, could be strictly classed as<br />

discouraging disposal in some cases and recovery in others.


environmental performance. The landfill tax has been highlighted as the reason<br />

behind many waste minimisation, recycling and segregation initiatives identified by<br />

the programme.<br />

In addition to this Kautto and Melanen explain that in Finland economic instruments<br />

(including the waste tax) have stimulated companies to increase the recovery <strong>of</strong><br />

waste, although in most cases the costs <strong>of</strong> waste management were relatively low. 981<br />

The authors argue that this can be at least partly explained by the fact that many <strong>of</strong><br />

the companies they studied were located in municipalities in which the municipal<br />

waste charges had traditionally been low. 982 When the charges had grown relatively<br />

rapidly in the late 1990s and the national waste tax had been implemented in 1996,<br />

this had given the firms a signal concerning anticipated developments, making them<br />

search for new ways to minimise wastes. Many <strong>of</strong> their interviewees also felt that<br />

taxation and other economic instruments are appropriate tools for enhancing ecoefficiency<br />

and sound waste management.<br />

The limited evidence base here seems to suggest that there is somewhat more <strong>of</strong> a<br />

link between taxation and a reduction in disposal <strong>of</strong> C&I wastes. Unfortunately no<br />

study has been found specifically concerning the evaluation <strong>of</strong> landfill bans in terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste minimisation, so no further analysis can be made. The evidence suggests<br />

that the environmental benefits from the policies in relation to C&I wastes are small<br />

but potentially have a further capacity for increase if the price signal is continued to<br />

be passed though at an appropriate level.<br />

52.6 Implementation Costs<br />

For a landfill ban the costs are essentially those associated with the design <strong>of</strong> the<br />

system, administration and publicity needed to inform the stakeholders affected by<br />

the ban i.e. landfill operators and wastes generators. These costs would also be<br />

applicable to landfill taxes. In addition there would also be the costs <strong>of</strong> measuring the<br />

weight <strong>of</strong> material disposed <strong>of</strong> at landfill, for example, by weighbridges.<br />

Several landfill taxes and bans limit the nature <strong>of</strong> waste by certain proxies to<br />

biodegradability such as:<br />

783<br />

� Limits on Total Organic Content (TOC);<br />

� Limits on Total Carbon Content; or<br />

� Limits on Calorific Value (CV).<br />

These all require some calculation or measurement to be taken. There will be some<br />

cost incurred by the agency setting up and administering this type <strong>of</strong> system. No<br />

specific financials were found in the literature, however.<br />

981 P. Kautto and M. Melanen (2004) How does industry respond to waste policy instruments – Finnish<br />

experiences, Journal <strong>of</strong> Cleaner Production, 12(1), 1-11<br />

982 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Additionally for incineration taxes, if not based on weight <strong>of</strong> material but pollutant<br />

levels, costs <strong>of</strong> measuring instruments and infrastructure on the plant would also be<br />

incurred.<br />

Furthermore there will be some costs associated in developing a system <strong>of</strong> regulation<br />

and enforcement. New regional <strong>of</strong>fices may need to be set up and staffed to monitor<br />

landfills or manage illegal dumping, for example – see Section 52.11.<br />

Moreover, the cost-effectiveness (in terms <strong>of</strong> net social benefit) is likely to be low if a<br />

ban on all waste is introduced. 983 This is because the marginal costs for waste<br />

diverted from landfill to another process will be expensive for some materials and / or<br />

streams, and is likely to exceed the benefits <strong>of</strong> such diversion. Where specific<br />

streams have a high negative environmental impact because <strong>of</strong> their nature, and<br />

there exists a cost effective alternative to manage the stream, bans may represent a<br />

closer approximation to what is socially optimal.<br />

52.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

In Austria the landfill tax has had a significant impact on the rate <strong>of</strong> technological<br />

change at landfills. In other countries, concerns over local pollution have been<br />

enough to stimulate legislation to incentivise the implementation <strong>of</strong> pollution<br />

abatement equipment at landfills. For example, the statutory regulations on landfill in<br />

Denmark require operators to manage their sites in an environmentally favourable<br />

way.<br />

However in relation to non-landfill technologies, a Dutch report concludes that little<br />

technical change has been seen in the Netherlands in terms <strong>of</strong> new incinerators, but<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> SRF abroad has increased. 984 Additionally, any link between the tax and<br />

recycling infrastructure was described as ‘ambiguous’.<br />

52.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

Although landfill taxes are not highly significant where sectoral turnover is concerned,<br />

some sectors are clearly affected more than others. The construction industry can be<br />

significantly affected, depending upon the nature <strong>of</strong> the tax regime, because it<br />

generates significant waste relative to turnover. The same applies for universities,<br />

and other sites where large numbers <strong>of</strong> people are domiciled and generating waste.<br />

Those areas where there are relatively low gate fees for waste disposal will see a<br />

higher percentage increase and thus ‘feel’ the effects <strong>of</strong> the tax to a greater extent. In<br />

England typical disposal fees pre-tax for municipal wastes, or non-inert industrial<br />

wastes were between £7-£25 (approx 11.2-40€) per tonne so that the tax implied an<br />

983 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005<br />

984 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.<br />

784<br />

29/09/09


increase <strong>of</strong> between 30-100%. In Austria the level <strong>of</strong> tax as a percentage <strong>of</strong> the<br />

disposal cost varies quite strongly across the employment sector. Therefore it is likely<br />

that some sectors will be more affected than others. 985<br />

Initially in France some rural areas faced much higher total costs for household waste<br />

due to greater distances to small landfill sites generally charging higher landfill gate<br />

fees per ton <strong>of</strong> waste. However, before 2004 in Austria, the differential in disposal<br />

costs at landfills, between those that had upgraded and those that had not complied<br />

with the regulations, resulted in a commercial advantage for those ‘hanging on’ until<br />

the last minute to comply. This promoted waste tourism, whereby waste generators<br />

found it cheaper to transport material across the country to sites that had not yet<br />

upgraded (despite the higher taxation levels).<br />

52.8.1 <strong>Waste</strong> Sector<br />

Ecotec reports that the landfill tax in England has had a major effect on the pricing<br />

structures <strong>of</strong> the waste management industry itself. For example, with skip hire firms,<br />

prices appear to have roughly doubled in the wake <strong>of</strong> the tax. For this reason, in the<br />

wake <strong>of</strong> the tax, waste delivered by small traders to civic amenity sites probably<br />

increased. Evidence suggests that waste from some home improvement projects<br />

were being taken to CA sites in hired vans instead <strong>of</strong> being disposed <strong>of</strong> in skips as<br />

might have been the case previously. This is not legal in the UK, where CA sites are<br />

reserved for household waste, and the practice led to the introduction <strong>of</strong> permitting<br />

schemes by local authorities to ensure that material delivered to their sites was not<br />

from tradespeople.<br />

52.8.2 Adaptive Strategies<br />

One would expect companies who assist in <strong>of</strong>fering the provision <strong>of</strong> advice concerning<br />

recycling and waste minimisation to benefit from the tax.<br />

52.8.3 Impacts on Employment<br />

In England, increased employment can be seen in the form <strong>of</strong> waste minimization<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficers, recycling contractors and operatives, and those associated with the<br />

environmental schemes associated with the landfill tax credits scheme.<br />

In France it was thought that sorting activities would see that greatest increase, with<br />

additional community schemes set up for disabled and ‘youth’ workers. However, the<br />

French also expressed concerns about the reduction <strong>of</strong> employment in waste<br />

management near its borders with waste being exported to countries with a lower<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> disposal.<br />

Attention should also be given to the employment effects <strong>of</strong> re-directing funds into<br />

waste management. For example, if a local authority spends more on waste<br />

management, and in doing so, employs more people in the process, it is diverting<br />

985 Ecotec (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.<br />

785<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


funds which it may have spent elsewhere hence reducing employment in other<br />

sectors such as health and education.<br />

52.8.4 Commerce<br />

In England service sector companies will have gained whilst manufacturing industries<br />

will have seen a net loss because the disposal costs will have been higher and the<br />

increased NI contributions less. However, this reveals only the static picture. In some<br />

enterprises, the signalling effect <strong>of</strong> the tax led to re-appraisal <strong>of</strong> waste management<br />

expenditures and, subsequently, to changes in behaviour which left the company in a<br />

better financial position after the tax than before. 986<br />

52.9 Complementary Policies<br />

As discussed in this section <strong>of</strong> the report, the effects <strong>of</strong> policies are very much linked.<br />

We describe each and how they relate to taxes and regulatory bans under the<br />

headings below.<br />

52.9.1 Pay by Use<br />

As disposal costs increase (and both taxes and bans have this effect), so the rationale<br />

for avoiding disposal increases. The potential for a rational structuring <strong>of</strong> charges<br />

under pay-by-use schemes increases as disposal costs increase, enabling charge<br />

structures to incentivise prevention and recycling in a manner consistent with the<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> service delivery.<br />

52.9.2 Producer Responsibility<br />

Many countries have indicated the importance <strong>of</strong> this policy in driving recycling<br />

initiatives and diverting waste from landfill. As with pay-by-use, the financial rationale<br />

for recycling and prevention is strengthened by higher avoided costs <strong>of</strong> disposal.<br />

52.9.3 Compulsory Collections <strong>of</strong> Biowaste / Pre-treatment<br />

In some jurisdictions, such as Massachusetts in the US, ‘landfill bans’ are<br />

implemented which are not, strictly speaking, bans. Local authorities comply with the<br />

ban through delivering source separation <strong>of</strong> materials specified as being banned from<br />

landfill. Rather than constituting a ban, these measures imply a requirement for<br />

source separation.<br />

Some countries with more ‘genuine’ bans in place do make use <strong>of</strong> requirements to<br />

source separate materials. In Austria the Ordinance on the Separate Collection <strong>of</strong><br />

Biowaste (1995) specifies materials which the householder must either compost at<br />

home, or must separate for collection by local authorities. The remained biowaste<br />

must be pre-treated to stabilise it before disposal in landfill. Since 1994 in the<br />

Netherlands, municipalities have the obligation to collect organic waste and the<br />

986 ECOTEC (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.<br />

786<br />

29/09/09


emaining residual waste separately. 987 This gave an enormous boost to the amount<br />

<strong>of</strong> household waste composted. In Catalonia (Spain) municipalities pay a lower rate <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill tax if there is a source separated food waste collection system in place.<br />

All these instruments will complement and support policies that ban biowaste from<br />

landfill (see Annexes 34.0 and 35.0).<br />

52.9.4 Energy Policies<br />

In Denmark the price <strong>of</strong> heat from EfW plants is discounted to insure that the use <strong>of</strong><br />

waste as a fuel is incentivised. This complements the ban on combustible materials<br />

from landfill.<br />

Similarly, in Sweden, where there is less tax on the combustion <strong>of</strong> wastes than for<br />

fossil based fuels, further incentive is also given to use waste to fuel the district<br />

heating systems.<br />

52.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

Landfill and incineration taxes are rarely set on the basis <strong>of</strong> externalities. The closest<br />

examples come from the early days <strong>of</strong> the UK experience, and the incineration tax in<br />

Norway. Elsewhere, taxes have tended to follow a preference ordering, without<br />

necessarily justifying this ordering.<br />

Bans are not efficient instruments. Arguably, they should not be sanctioned,<br />

particularly from the perspective <strong>of</strong> economic efficiency. As the OECD puts it: 988<br />

787<br />

191. From an economic perspective, introducing a ban on landfilling is<br />

equivalent to stating that the value <strong>of</strong> the environmental harm caused by the<br />

landfilling is infinitely high. While this can be defendable for certain types <strong>of</strong><br />

hazardous waste, it is much more difficult to see the theoretical underpinning<br />

for a ban on the landfilling <strong>of</strong> paper waste . whether or not it has been<br />

collected separately.<br />

192. For such waste categories, it would seem more relevant from an<br />

economic perspective to lift the ban and to set a tax on landfilling that more<br />

closely reflected the environmental externalities that actually would be caused<br />

if the waste was to be landfilled. For paper wastes, the relevant tax rate could<br />

very well be considerably lower than the current rate <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Tax.<br />

Taxes have more to recommend them.<br />

Even so, as in the UK, taxes tend to be used in a pragmatic way to deliver waste<br />

management objectives, and although some taxes can seem quite high, to some<br />

extent, they can be perceived as second best policies where, instead <strong>of</strong> taxes on<br />

987 Since the year 2000 several municipalities, especially the large ones like Utrecht and Rotterdam,<br />

have asked for and got an exemption from this law. They do not have to collect waste separately in<br />

some parts <strong>of</strong> the municipality if the quality <strong>of</strong> collected organic waste is too low.<br />

988 OECD (2005) Instrument Mixes Used to Address Household <strong>Waste</strong>: Further Analyses and Additional<br />

Case Study, ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)4/REV1, Paris: OECD.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


disposal and subsidies for recycling, higher taxes are used to represent the<br />

differential between disposal and recycling.<br />

52.10.1 Product Pricing<br />

In most cases it is difficult to know exactly what effect the tax has had on product<br />

prices. It is almost certainly true that the impact on end product prices is negligible<br />

because for most sectors, the tax expressed as a percentage <strong>of</strong> turnover is small, and<br />

although some evidence <strong>of</strong> this relates to taxes that are now at much higher levels<br />

than when the analysis was carried out, the evidence suggests that the levels would<br />

have needed to be some orders <strong>of</strong> magnitude higher to affect prices. 989 For example,<br />

in Austria there is no evidence <strong>of</strong> an effect on product prices arising from the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> the landfill tax. 990 Another good indicator <strong>of</strong> this is that whilst<br />

environmental taxes may be accounting for a growing share <strong>of</strong> tax revenues in some<br />

countries, the total tax take from landfill taxes tends to be a very small proportion <strong>of</strong><br />

overall tax revenues. With the K tax at £32 per tonne in 2008-9, the total tax take<br />

was less than £1 billion <strong>of</strong> a total tax take in excess <strong>of</strong> £500 billion.<br />

52.10.2 Trade<br />

The Ecotec report indicates the awareness <strong>of</strong> no major impacts on trade. 991 As<br />

regards waste itself, the costs <strong>of</strong> waste management already vary across countries<br />

depending upon the legislative (regulatory) framework and the mix <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management options available. Therefore the trade or movement <strong>of</strong> waste will vary<br />

depending on the adjacent countries regulatory conditions, and most importantly for<br />

inter-continental trade, the transportation costs <strong>of</strong> waste (which are relatively high).<br />

On mainland Europe, tax differentials, or bans imposed unilaterally, can have an<br />

impact on trade where facilities are defined as recovery. For example, waste moves<br />

across borders in pursuit <strong>of</strong> lower gate fees in different EU Member States. The <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Framework Directive now allows for Member States to limit movement <strong>of</strong> waste to<br />

protect their own incineration capacity for municipal waste. This could have the effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> limiting some <strong>of</strong> the effects <strong>of</strong> different prices across Member States.<br />

52.10.3 Recycling / <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Industry<br />

The most significant observable effect <strong>of</strong> the policies will be to grow the recycling<br />

industry, so notwithstanding the increased costs for disposal <strong>of</strong> ‘final residues’, the<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> services are still likely to fall. The same could be said for the incineration<br />

industry unless there is also an incineration tax present.<br />

989 See Ecotec (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes<br />

& Charges in the EU.<br />

990 Ecotec (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.<br />

991 Ecotec (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.<br />

788<br />

29/09/09


52.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

52.11.1 Illegal Dumping Sites, Fly tipping and <strong>Waste</strong> Stream Transfer<br />

In the Ecotec report on EU taxes and charges it was mentioned that there were<br />

substantial numbers <strong>of</strong> illegal landfills or dumping sites in pre-tax France. Once the<br />

tax was introduced these sites could still be taxed, but there seemed to be a<br />

reluctance to prosecute and have the sites shut down; the reason for this is<br />

unclear. 992<br />

In England, Local Authorities (LAs) bear the costs <strong>of</strong> clearing up waste that is flytipped<br />

on public land. 993 Some claim to have experienced increases in fly-tipping.<br />

However, it is also suggested that this could be due to a greater awareness <strong>of</strong> the<br />

problem post-tax, and that there was a poor baseline, because local authorities<br />

previously defined fly-tipping in different ways.<br />

Moreover, in Germany the introduction <strong>of</strong> the landfill ban on untreated wastes has<br />

stimulated the illegal dumping <strong>of</strong> untreated waste and waste to unlicensed sites such<br />

as quarries (see Annex 53.0).<br />

Eunomia’s household waste prevention report states that there was some concern<br />

that waste which was previously in the commercial and industrial stream might enter<br />

the household stream through being taken to civic amenity sites. 994 The effect is that<br />

municipal waste almost certainly increased as a result <strong>of</strong> the tax. This resulted in the<br />

tightening up <strong>of</strong> procedures at HWRCs to stop the switch <strong>of</strong> C&I wastes into the<br />

municipal stream. For example, the drivers <strong>of</strong> any vans now entering HWRCs in<br />

England have to produce a pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> address, copy <strong>of</strong> hire certificate, and demonstrate<br />

to the site operators what is in the vehicle on entrance.<br />

52.11.2 Illegal Administration Fees<br />

Ecotec also reports that the trade body SNADE tried to use its member’s dominant<br />

position in the market to implement an administration fee to the costs <strong>of</strong> disposal.<br />

This resulted in a substantially hike in the tax in 1993. This activity was illegal and<br />

brought to the competition court whereby the group was fined on the grounds <strong>of</strong> free<br />

market competition and abuse <strong>of</strong> dominant position. This was discovered to be a<br />

sensitive issue and stakeholders are now reluctant to discuss the tax, however, no<br />

repeat incidents have been reported.<br />

992 ECOTEC (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.<br />

993 Eunomia et al (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report<br />

for Defra.<br />

994 Eunomia et al (2007) Household <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention <strong>Policy</strong> Side Research Programme, Final Report<br />

for Defra<br />

789<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


52.12 <strong>Waste</strong> Taxes and Bans (C&D waste)<br />

The compositional and arisings data for the Construction and Demolition sector is<br />

poor and thus there are limited studies to draw on for relevant information.<br />

Table 52-7 below indicates that the taxation mechanisms vary significantly between<br />

countries. For example, some keep the same rate as for MSW / C&I, some have<br />

separate rates for C&D wastes specifically, others differentiate the inert fraction and<br />

several do not indicate any specifics at all.<br />

52.13 Environmental Benefits<br />

The environmental benefits from waste prevention <strong>of</strong> C&D wastes stem from where<br />

re-use is promoted either on-site or at sites much closer than landfills. The dominant<br />

factor here being the emissions associated with the transportation <strong>of</strong> the high<br />

volumes and weight <strong>of</strong> materials. The actual switch away from landfill is not very<br />

relevant here as there are very small quantities <strong>of</strong> rapidly degrading materials (i.e.<br />

food waste) disposed <strong>of</strong> in the waste stream, hence methane emissions will be<br />

negligible. <strong>Waste</strong> volumes from the C&D sector are obviously going to be linked to the<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> construction activity occurring. Thus any trends in waste arisings must be<br />

considered with this in light.<br />

The only evaluation information additional to that discussed in Section 46.0 which<br />

included any analysis <strong>of</strong> the impact <strong>of</strong> landfill taxation on C&D wastes concluded the<br />

following: 995<br />

790<br />

� In England the waste stream which has been most affected by the tax has<br />

been C&D;<br />

� The pre-tax gate-fee for inert wastes was <strong>of</strong> the order £0-2 (0-3.2€) per tonne.<br />

So in percentage terms, the introduction <strong>of</strong> the tax at £2 (€3.2) has had a<br />

significant effect (>100% increase);<br />

� After a survey <strong>of</strong> operators was conducted, post-implementation, the total<br />

volumes <strong>of</strong> material landfilled appeared to drop considerably, however the<br />

preliminary data was thought to be <strong>of</strong> low quality;<br />

� The arrival <strong>of</strong> the tax has seen the further development <strong>of</strong> an industry recycling<br />

materials suitable for (re)use in construction (previously this was noticeable<br />

principally in areas where landfill void space was scarce). Alongside the tax,<br />

other initiatives may also have assisted in this development; and<br />

� In Austria the Construction industry will clearly be strongly affected by this<br />

waste tax in terms <strong>of</strong> volume <strong>of</strong> waste being produced, however the rate for<br />

demolition waste is low and therefore the burden should be acceptable.<br />

Particularly in the case <strong>of</strong> construction materials, the waste tax may have been<br />

important in promoting recovery and reuse. 996<br />

995 ECOTEC (2001) Study on the Economic and Environmental Implications <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> Env. Taxes &<br />

Charges in the EU.<br />

29/09/09


Table 52-7: Summary <strong>of</strong> Measures by <strong>Policy</strong> Approach (C&D waste)<br />

Country Country Country Landfill Landfill Landfill Tax Tax Tax Tax Tax Tax Rate Rate ( (€ ( ( € € per per tonne tonne) tonne<br />

Comments:<br />

Comments:<br />

South Australia 1993 5.4<br />

Non-metropolitan<br />

waste<br />

Western Australia 1998 3.4 Inert waste<br />

Austria 1989 8 C&D<br />

Finland 1996 30 As MSW / C&I<br />

Germany x X As MSW<br />

Hungary x X As MSW<br />

Italy 1996 10.3997 C&D (Industrial)<br />

Belgium-Flanders 1990 -<br />

Reduction for<br />

construction waste<br />

Belgium-Wallonia x X As MSW<br />

Denmark 1987 50 As MSW<br />

France 1992 X MSW and C&I only<br />

The Netherlands 1996 14<br />

Non-combustible<br />

waste<br />

Norway 1999 40 Unclear<br />

As MSW – but<br />

Sweden 2000 43<br />

reductions for<br />

landfill construction<br />

material<br />

Czech Republic 1991 16 Unclear<br />

Estonia 1990 8 Unclear<br />

Slovakia 1992 0.26 Inert waste<br />

Slovenia 2001 Unclear<br />

Spain – Catalonia 2003 Unclear<br />

Less than MSW /<br />

C&I<br />

United Kingdom 1996 3.2 Inert waste<br />

Note: where the word unclear appears, we have not been able to establish the rate for C&D waste.<br />

52.14 Lessons Learned (MSW)<br />

The main lessons learned, as expanded on below, can be summarised as follows.<br />

� Taxes are rarely based on externalities – the policy is generally used in the context<br />

<strong>of</strong> other instruments to achieve specific objectives;<br />

� Reflecting the above, few jurisdictions apply taxes in a manner that targets the<br />

sources <strong>of</strong> pollution which are generated by treatments;<br />

996 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.<br />

997 Highest rate is given. Lowest rate set regionally can be €1.<br />

791<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


� Landfill bans are <strong>of</strong>ten applied alongside high landfill taxes. The principle effect<br />

appears to be to shift from landfill to incineration / other forms <strong>of</strong> residual<br />

treatment;<br />

� The effect <strong>of</strong> landfill taxes on waste prevention seems limited. They are more likely<br />

to have a positive effect on waste prevention where the price signal is passed<br />

through to the waste producer (PBU);<br />

� Landfill bans or restrictions, when applied alone, may have an impact on waste<br />

prevention, and it may be the case that this impact is greater where landfill is<br />

relatively cheap compared to the alternatives;<br />

� Landfill and incineration taxes can improve recycling but the extent <strong>of</strong> the impact<br />

depends upon the extent to which other policies have already led to the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> the activity;<br />

� Furthermore, if the policies are to decrease pollution they must incentivise the<br />

shift to a better performing alternative method <strong>of</strong> treatment (via the substitution<br />

price effect) or make it more cost effective for plant operators to include a high<br />

level <strong>of</strong> abatement equipment in their facilities;<br />

� Landfill bans and restrictions can be implemented either rapidly, with exemptions<br />

in place where infrastructure is not adequately developed, or with a long lead<br />

time, so that infrastructure has time to come on stream. The former has the merit<br />

<strong>of</strong> being less likely to be politically derailed, but in order to prevent repeated resort<br />

being made to exemptions, these exemptions should be expensive to those who<br />

seek them.<br />

52.15 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

Success factors in the way that taxes have been introduced have been attributed to<br />

the following:<br />

792<br />

� the analytical and policy ground was well prepared in advance <strong>of</strong> the tax;<br />

� the consultation process helped defuse potential criticisms;<br />

� the tax was based on externality estimates, which was acceptable to<br />

economically knowledgeable commentators;<br />

� fiscal neutrality <strong>of</strong> the tax (the revenue was used to reduce taxes elsewhere in<br />

the economy); and<br />

� the move to a weight-based tax and the use <strong>of</strong> revenues for environmental<br />

remediation schemes that were favoured by the environmental lobby.<br />

Complementary Policies such as those described in Section 52.9 are very much to be<br />

recommended with the implementation <strong>of</strong> any taxes / bans that affect the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

the residual stream. This is so that other avenues for the disposal <strong>of</strong> the material<br />

become available. In addition, the following are recommended;<br />

� The implementation <strong>of</strong> bans and levies needs to pre-empt the potential for<br />

additional illegal behaviour. Changing price structures leads to changed incentives<br />

to avoid the effects <strong>of</strong> the instruments. Regulatory enforcement needs to choke<br />

<strong>of</strong>f such activities.<br />

29/09/09


� A clear rationale for the proposed policy needs to be in place.<br />

� Complementary policies should encourage development <strong>of</strong> alternatives to the<br />

taxed / banned / restricted activity.<br />

� In the case <strong>of</strong> taxes, announcements should occur in advance <strong>of</strong> the instrument<br />

coming into force.<br />

� In the case <strong>of</strong> bans and restrictions, the policy needs to be capable <strong>of</strong> being<br />

implemented and enforced.<br />

793<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


53.0 Landfill Ban (German Case Study)<br />

53.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Disposal Ordinance<br />

794<br />

29/09/09<br />

Ordinance 998<br />

The policy “landfill ban” means the restriction <strong>of</strong> the disposal <strong>of</strong> untreated municipal<br />

waste, and other waste streams with certain carbon content, in landfills. In the<br />

following chapters the policy on the German landfill ban will be described.<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Ordinance (AbfAblV) is intended to avoid climate-damaging<br />

emissions and landfill leachate containing hazardous substances, in order to mitigate<br />

the environmental impact associated with municipal waste. In order to achieve this<br />

objective it specifies, amongst other things, which thermally or mechanically<br />

biologically treated wastes may be deposited in landfill; this is known as the input<br />

criteria. According to the <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Ordinance the disposal <strong>of</strong> untreated waste in<br />

municipal landfill had to cease by 31.05.2005 (Article 6, Section 2, No. 1 <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Disposal Ordinance).<br />

53.2 Where Has the <strong>Policy</strong> Been Applied and Why?<br />

The policy has been applied in Germany since 1 June 2005.<br />

Until 1 June 2005, a significant amount <strong>of</strong> household waste in Germany was still<br />

disposed in landfills. This was a consequence <strong>of</strong> the fact that the disposal <strong>of</strong> waste in<br />

landfills is far cheaper than the cost <strong>of</strong> recovering materials, or <strong>of</strong> energy generation<br />

from waste through incineration or co-incineration.<br />

As the ban entered into force, and as a result <strong>of</strong> the falling amount <strong>of</strong> residual waste,<br />

municipalities in many German regions which were owners <strong>of</strong> the landfills tried to<br />

reduce the problems <strong>of</strong> overcapacity by lowering the prices for disposal before June<br />

2005, thus trying to stimulate disposal to landfill, and generate additional revenue in<br />

the period before the ban was implemented.<br />

In some German regions, municipal waste incinerators had been the main fate <strong>of</strong><br />

household waste for many years. The treatment <strong>of</strong> household waste in modern<br />

municipal waste incinerators (with acceptable technologies according to the legal<br />

obligations) is much more expensive than the simple disposal in landfills. Therefore<br />

many cities and counties have developed and realized regional waste management<br />

concepts (includes measures to encourage waste prevention, waste separation and<br />

recycling, and pay by use schemes incorporating incentives to reduce the total<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> waste, as well as the proportion <strong>of</strong> unrecycled material 999) to reduce the<br />

998 Ordinance on Environmentally Compatible Storage <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> from Human Settlements<br />

(Abfallablagerungsverordnung - AbfAblV) <strong>of</strong> 20.2.2001, Federal Law Gazette pg. 305.<br />

999 For more details see Annex 9.0.


overall costs <strong>of</strong> household waste management and minimise the cost burden for<br />

single households.<br />

The disposal <strong>of</strong> household waste is regulated through the Technical Instructions on<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> from Human Settlements (the Technische Anleitung Siedlungsabfall, or TASi).<br />

The TASi has been amended by the Ordinance on the Storage <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>s<br />

and on Biological Treatment Processes (Abfallablagerungsverordnung), which entered<br />

into force in March 2001. According to the TASi, the disposal <strong>of</strong> untreated wastes in<br />

landfills has been forbidden from 1 June 2005.<br />

The reasons for the landfill ban <strong>of</strong> untreated household waste, and <strong>of</strong> other waste<br />

flows with a specified organic carbon content in Germany are related to the following<br />

facts:<br />

795<br />

� Tremendous environmental problems were caused by landfills in the 70s, 80s<br />

and 90s, and a serious shortage <strong>of</strong> landfill capacity was emerging in regions<br />

with high densities <strong>of</strong> population (“waste emergency” was a popular headline<br />

in German newspapers);<br />

� Germany is a country with a high population density in many regions. Serious<br />

political discussions and ongoing debates about the problems <strong>of</strong> landfill arose<br />

during the last three decades in many <strong>of</strong> these regions, e.g., the spectacular<br />

case <strong>of</strong> “Messel fosse” (close to Darmstadt), which is a world famous place <strong>of</strong><br />

discovery for prehistoric fossils, was foreseen, until the early 90s, as a new<br />

large-scale landfill. Due to tremendous civil engagement the authorities were<br />

forced to give up the landfill plan and today the area is now preserved for the<br />

scientific community;<br />

� Considerable technical developments in the field <strong>of</strong> recycling, pre-treatment <strong>of</strong><br />

waste and waste incineration; and<br />

� The large scale <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gas emissions from landfills led also to focus on<br />

a landfill ban due to national greenhouse gas reduction plans.<br />

Therefore the long-term issue was mitigated by introducing a landfill ban <strong>of</strong> untreated<br />

waste, with the target for implementation set for 2005.<br />

53.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The Federal German Ministry <strong>of</strong> Environment was responsible for the implementation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the legislation in agreement with the German Länder. The German Länder are in<br />

charge for the ongoing control <strong>of</strong> the implementation and management in practice in<br />

compliance with the legislation.<br />

53.4 Evaluation Studies Available<br />

For general aspects see:<br />

� Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen,<br />

SRU) Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2008, July 2008 (See:<br />

http://www.umweltrat.de for further information).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


796<br />

� Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen,<br />

SRU) Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2004, July 2004 Council <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen, SRU)<br />

Environmental Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2002, July 2002.<br />

For the reduction <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gases by the landfill ban and other measures in<br />

Germany see:<br />

� Contribution <strong>of</strong> waste management to climate protection and its potentials<br />

(Beitrag der Abfallwirtschaft zum Klimaschutz und mögliche Potenziale),<br />

Dehoust, G. (Öko-Institut e.V.); Umweltbundesamt workshop „Energy from<br />

waste – a significant contribution to climate protection” 6 November 2006,<br />

Berlin.<br />

For the development <strong>of</strong> waste quantities in intermediate storages see:<br />

� Further decrease <strong>of</strong> quantities in intermediate storages, EUWID from 15 July<br />

2008.<br />

53.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The landfill ban has reduced the share <strong>of</strong> landfill for untreated waste since the<br />

Nineties until the final implementation <strong>of</strong> the ban in June 2005. The Federal Ministry<br />

<strong>of</strong> Environment has announced a reduction <strong>of</strong> 31 million tons CO2-equivalents until<br />

2010 (compared to 1990) resulting from the landfill ban, and further measures for<br />

landfill gas collection and energy recovery. 1000<br />

Furthermore member states <strong>of</strong> the EU-27 with a low share <strong>of</strong> landfill are showing the<br />

highest rates regarding recycling/recovery <strong>of</strong> municipal waste. Concerning the issue<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste prevention, a moderate reduction <strong>of</strong> the waste intensity (amount <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

per GDP) has been detected for Germany. So, a slight decoupling <strong>of</strong> waste production<br />

from GDP could be said to have occurred, not necessarily related only to the landfill<br />

ban. 1001<br />

53.6 Implementation Costs<br />

According to the BDE, the Technische Anleitung Siedlungsabfall - TaSi (incorporating<br />

the announcement <strong>of</strong> the disposal ban from 1 June 2005) has promoted investments<br />

<strong>of</strong> 20 Billion Euro in new treatment, recycling and incineration plants since 1993 in<br />

Germany. 1002<br />

1000 Facts about sustainable waste management, September 2007, www.bmu.de/5886.<br />

1001 Council <strong>of</strong> Environmental Advisors (Sachverständigen Rat für Umweltfragen, SRU) Environmental<br />

Report („Umweltgutachten“) 2008, July 2008 (See: http://www.umweltrat.de for further information).<br />

1002 BDE: Bundesverband der Deutschen Entsorgungswirtschaft, EUWID, Nr. 28. 12. 07.2005.<br />

29/09/09


53.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

The quite demanding requirements <strong>of</strong> the TaSi were eased through use <strong>of</strong> a long<br />

transition period (1993 to 1 June 2005) to give the authorities enough time to<br />

develop new waste management concepts, and investments in new technologies and<br />

installations.<br />

Higher costs for dealing with waste provide the most obvious incentive for private<br />

households and communities, respectively, to foster waste prevention and, obviously,<br />

where increasing costs relate to disposal, to a much greater extent, waste separation<br />

and recycling.<br />

Knowing the TaSi deadline (1 June 2005) for many years, fundamental changes were<br />

introduced in Germany concerning household waste management over the<br />

intervening 10 – 15 years. In 1999 about 49 % <strong>of</strong> household waste was recycled. By<br />

2003 the recycling rate had reached 61 %. Furthermore the rate <strong>of</strong> waste treatment<br />

in municipal waste incinerators (a more expensive, but better way for the<br />

environment) increased, and the rate <strong>of</strong> disposal in landfills fell. The increase in<br />

incineration is shown in Table 53-1.<br />

Table 53-1: Treatment <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong> in Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Incinerators in<br />

Germany 1003<br />

797<br />

Year<br />

Year<br />

Municipal Municipal waste<br />

waste<br />

Incinerators<br />

Incinerators<br />

(Number) (Number)<br />

(Number)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Input Input Capacity Capacity in in<br />

in<br />

Germany Germany in in in total total (in<br />

(in<br />

1,000 1,000 tons/y) tons/y)<br />

tons/y)<br />

Average Average Input Input Capacity<br />

Capacity<br />

per per Incinerator Incinerator (in<br />

(in<br />

1,000 1,000 tons/Y) tons/Y)<br />

tons/Y)<br />

1990 48 9,200 191<br />

1992 50 9,500 190<br />

1993 49 9,420 192<br />

1995 52 10,870 202<br />

1998 53 11,900 225<br />

2000 61 13,999 230<br />

2005 67 16,900 252<br />

2007 1004 72 17,779 247<br />

1003 Daten zur Umwelt, Der Zustand der Umwelt in Deutschland, Ausgabe 2005, Umweltbundesamt<br />

Berlin.<br />

1004 Estimated figure for 2007.


In addition to incineration capacity increasing, the capacity <strong>of</strong> MBT treatments has<br />

also increased. In some respects, the pace <strong>of</strong> this development has been more rapid<br />

than that for incineration. The principle legislation allowing the development <strong>of</strong> the<br />

technology was not finalised until 2001.<br />

A report by the ASA states that there are currently 46 MBT plants operated in<br />

Germany. These plants pre-treat approximately 25 % <strong>of</strong> the total municipal solid<br />

waste (approximately 6 million tonnes). The pre-treatment processes generate an<br />

estimated 3 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> a high calorific material with a biogenic content <strong>of</strong> some<br />

50 %. 1005<br />

53.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

Of course, the disposal ban concerning landfills could not be realized free <strong>of</strong> any<br />

costs. The increase in costs for private households was a key argument against the<br />

demanding requirements <strong>of</strong> the TaSi and its consequences. However, in many cities<br />

and counties, it was demonstrated that, in practice, the realization <strong>of</strong> intelligent waste<br />

management concepts (waste separation, local waste charges with incentives for<br />

waste prevention etc.) delivered positive results. This means, perhaps surprisingly,<br />

that cost savings could be achieved in the overall waste management costs in a given<br />

region. So, even if the disposal costs per tonne increased as a result <strong>of</strong> the measure,<br />

the costs per household did not necessarily increase in the same way because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

possibility <strong>of</strong> generating a dynamic incentive to reduce waste quantities, and increase<br />

recycling rates. This highlights the important role <strong>of</strong> higher disposal costs incentivising<br />

municipalities to introduce measures such as pay by use to avoid the rising costs <strong>of</strong><br />

disposal. 1006<br />

In the county Darmstadt-Dieburg for instance (see Annex 9.0) reductions <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

costs for the households are currently under serious consideration <strong>of</strong> the authorities<br />

due to the successful overall waste management system.<br />

53.9 Complementary Policies<br />

A landfill tax policy could deliver similar results to a landfill ban depending upon the<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> the tax per tonne <strong>of</strong> disposed waste. Under German market conditions, a<br />

landfill tax <strong>of</strong> the order € 100 per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste would be necessary to achieve<br />

similar results to those <strong>of</strong> the landfill ban. Depending on the region, and for instance<br />

1005 ASA (Arbeitsgemeinschaft St<strong>of</strong>fspezifische Abfallbehandlung) (2008) The Road to MBT Technology,<br />

December 2008; see also T. Grundmann and M. Balhar (2008) Status quo and Perspectives <strong>of</strong><br />

Mechnaical Biological <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment (MBT) in Germany, February 2009.<br />

1006 Interestingly, in Landkreis Schweinfurt, the ban on landfilling <strong>of</strong> untreated waste was cited as a<br />

major reason for enhancing the sophistication, and strengthening the incentives within, a charging<br />

scheme incentivising household waste reduction. The authority anticipated having to pay higher costs<br />

for disposal <strong>of</strong> waste to incineration, and in anticipation, sought to incentivise more segregation and<br />

waste reduction activities (see Eunomia (2003), <strong>Waste</strong> Collection: To Charge or Not to Charge? A Final<br />

report to IWM (EB), http://www.eunomia.co.uk/Charging%20report.pdf.).<br />

798<br />

29/09/09


the costs for disposal in municipal waste incinerators, an even higher tax rate might<br />

have been necessary.<br />

53.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The overall driving force for a change in waste management is the fact that the<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> household waste in municipal waste incinerators could be up to 10<br />

times higher per ton than disposal on landfills (about 170 – 250 Euro/ton compared<br />

to about 20 – 40 Euro/ton). As a consequence waste prevention and recycling look<br />

better from an economic point <strong>of</strong> view, because the cheap landfill option is no longer<br />

part <strong>of</strong> the market, as the ban precludes its use.<br />

53.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

Within the last few years serious criminal activities were uncovered mainly in the<br />

eastern German States regarding dumping <strong>of</strong> untreated waste in landfills as well as<br />

quarries. The scale <strong>of</strong> these criminal activities amounts to several hundred thousand<br />

tons <strong>of</strong> waste and proves that in some German States the authorities have a serious<br />

control problem due to <strong>of</strong>ten inexperienced staff with uncertainties regarding the<br />

definite role <strong>of</strong> the different legal bodies. Nevertheless it is interesting to note that<br />

these criminal cases were mainly uncovered by private detective bureaus engaged by<br />

South German companies which are running recycling and incineration plants – and<br />

have problems with an underperformance <strong>of</strong> their capacities. 1007 , 1008<br />

53.12 Lessons Learned<br />

Not much time has passed since the implementation <strong>of</strong> the ban, but the overall<br />

success <strong>of</strong> the policy could be said to be high.<br />

53.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

The essential elements for the policy “landfill ban” are an ambitious and precise<br />

national waste management plan with definite targets and appropriate work plans.<br />

The landfill ban must be embedded in a mid term phase out over time and<br />

incorporate action plans for incineration and recycling capacities in the country. The<br />

local communities need clear advice and support by the government to plan and<br />

come out with the right policies (e.g. “pay as you throw”) on the local level.<br />

1007 EUWID from 8.7.2008.<br />

1008 EUWID from 22.7 2008.<br />

799<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


54.0 <strong>Waste</strong> Levies and Bans (Belgium-Flanders<br />

Case Study)<br />

54.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

In Flanders two central policies can be defined to discourage disposal.<br />

800<br />

� Levies on incineration and on landfill give financial incentives to avoid final<br />

disposal; and<br />

� Direct landfill and incineration bans exclude final disposal for a range <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

types.<br />

Both policies have the same final objective. By avoiding disposal waste has either to<br />

be recycled or its production has to be prevented (direct prevention). The measure<br />

indirectly promotes social prevention as well, if the waste which cannot be landfilled<br />

or incinerated has to be fit for recycling.<br />

54.2 Reasons for Implementation<br />

The VLAREA, the Flemish law on waste management, excludes three waste treatment<br />

applications, i.e. D2 (Land treatment like biodegradation <strong>of</strong> liquid or sludgy discards<br />

in soils, etc.), D3 (Deep injection such as injection <strong>of</strong> pumpable discards into wells,<br />

salt domes or naturally occurring repositories, etc.) and D11 (Incineration at sea,<br />

which is in any case already prohibited by EU legislation and international<br />

conventions).<br />

In addition, for certain waste streams, landfill is forbidden, because <strong>of</strong> the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

the wastes, or because the possibility clearly exists to treat it through a means higher<br />

in the waste hierarchy. For some waste streams, both landfill and incineration are<br />

forbidden, which means that at least one preparatory sorting activity has to be<br />

applied to it.<br />

Over and above this, landfills and incineration plants have acceptance criteria<br />

included in their permits to operate.<br />

Landfill and incineration levies are imposed on a wide variety <strong>of</strong> waste streams and<br />

disposal operations. Some <strong>of</strong> the levies have been increasing over the years, but all <strong>of</strong><br />

them are automatically linked to an index <strong>of</strong> consumption prices (otherwise known as<br />

the Retail Price Index or RPI).<br />

54.2.1 Landfill and Incineration bans<br />

Landfill is forbidden for:<br />

� Unsorted household waste;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> collected for the purpose <strong>of</strong> recovery;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> that is, due to its nature, quantity and homogeneity, fit for recycling;<br />

� Incinerable sorting residues from household and comparable waste; and<br />

29/09/09


801<br />

� Old and expired medication.<br />

Incineration is forbidden for:<br />

� Selectively collected waste fit for material recovery or recycling, with the<br />

exception <strong>of</strong> some types <strong>of</strong> biowaste if they have a calorific value above 11.5<br />

MJ/kg and are used for the creation <strong>of</strong> renewable energy;<br />

� Unsorted industrial waste; and<br />

� Unsorted household waste.<br />

A peculiarity <strong>of</strong> Flemish legislation is the possibility for the Flemish minister to allow<br />

for exceptions from these obligations, on a case-by-case basis, for technical reasons<br />

(mainly due to treatment capacity issues).<br />

54.2.2 Landfill and Incineration levies<br />

The Flemish landfill and incineration levies are one <strong>of</strong> the most complex systems in<br />

the EU, with 37 different regimes and tariffs. Illegal landfill and incineration is<br />

suppressed with an indexed levy <strong>of</strong> €150 euro/tonne.<br />

The levies vary based on the possibility to apply more environmentally friendly<br />

alternatives for the treatment <strong>of</strong> the waste, or to promote recycling. Recycling<br />

residues that are landfilled or incinerated have a lighter levy than the same material<br />

which is landfilled or incinerated directly.<br />

To define ‘recycling residue’ the legislation includes 21 definitions, with percentages<br />

evolving from 3% <strong>of</strong> weight for the treatment <strong>of</strong> bottom ashes or garden waste, 5% <strong>of</strong><br />

weight for e.g. plastic, wood, paper… up to 25% for used solvents or shredder<br />

residues from scrap treatment. For some waste streams for which no BAT alternative<br />

is present a zero levy is imposed.<br />

Levies are imposed on the treatment installations, with the aim that they cover this<br />

cost through the treatment costs charged to the producer, in order to respect the<br />

polluter pays principle. <strong>Waste</strong> collectors are also subjected to the levy for the fraction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the collected waste which is disposed outside <strong>of</strong> Flanders. If comparable levies<br />

exist outside Flanders, the Flemish levy can be diminished accordingly, but never<br />

becomes a negative value.<br />

The treatment installations have to report the treated quantities <strong>of</strong> waste every<br />

trimester, and have to pay the levy accordingly.<br />

54.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

OVAM is involved in the calculation and the collection <strong>of</strong> the levies, and in the<br />

inspection.<br />

AMI, the Flemish environmental inspectorate, is responsible for the control on the<br />

landfill and incineration bans.<br />

Municipalities have as well an inspection competence, and are involved as they can<br />

install a surcharge on levies imposed on installation on their territory.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The revenues <strong>of</strong> the levies are destined for the MINA-fund, to fund all kinds <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental programmes.<br />

54.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

On the website <strong>of</strong> OVAM www.ovam.be several manuals and FAQ files can be found<br />

on the practical aspects <strong>of</strong> the levies (in Dutch).<br />

OVAM (2007) Tarieven en capaciteiten voor storten en verbranden (actualisatie tot<br />

2006, evolutie en prognose). This is a yearly report on tariffs for landfill and<br />

incineration plants and on available, and foreseen, capacities. It includes, each year,<br />

a comparison between the net costs and the levies for each type <strong>of</strong> treatment.<br />

54.4.1 Environmental Benefits<br />

The goal <strong>of</strong> the levies is to discourage final disposal and to make landfill, which is at<br />

the bottom <strong>of</strong> the waste treatment hierarchy, more expensive than incineration. As<br />

Figure 54-1 shows, this situation exists for household waste, but this is not quite the<br />

case for industrial waste.<br />

Figure 54-1: Operational Costs and Levies for Landfill and Incineration in Flanders<br />

euro/ton<br />

802<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

landfill<br />

hazardous waste<br />

costs and levies for waste disposal 2006<br />

landfill<br />

industrial waste<br />

incineration<br />

low caloric<br />

industrial waste<br />

incineration<br />

high caloric<br />

industrial waste<br />

tarif levy<br />

The levies for landfill usually equal or exceed the pre-levy costs for landfilling, while<br />

the levies for incineration are merely a small correction on a relatively high pre-levy<br />

cost.<br />

Hazardous waste is incinerated in specialised plants, but the costs are very much<br />

dependent on the nature <strong>of</strong> the waste so that a comparison with the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

landfilling is not meaningful. Moreover, landfill and incineration do not compete as<br />

such in the market for hazardous waste since the waste streams usually follow<br />

different routes.<br />

landfill<br />

household waste<br />

incineration<br />

household waste<br />

landfill inert waste


Even with high landfill levies, the total price for landfilling <strong>of</strong> industrial waste remains<br />

more attractive than incineration. A zero levy for incineration would not rectify this<br />

situation. Even after 27 years <strong>of</strong> levies with shifting and augmenting levies on landfill<br />

and incineration this undesired effect has not been corrected, and other policy<br />

instruments have to be applied to avoid industrial waste being landfilled.<br />

Figure 54-2 and Figure 54-3 show how the landfilling and incineration <strong>of</strong> waste has<br />

changed over time. Incineration <strong>of</strong> household waste remains stable in absolute<br />

quantities whilst incineration <strong>of</strong> industrial waste has slowly increased. Compared with<br />

the total production <strong>of</strong> industrial waste, incineration remains marginal. Landfill is still<br />

the more widely applied disposal technique than incineration for industrial waste.<br />

Figure 54-2: Evolution in Landfill <strong>of</strong> Household and Industrial <strong>Waste</strong> in Flanders<br />

kton<br />

803<br />

7.000,00<br />

6.000,00<br />

5.000,00<br />

4.000,00<br />

3.000,00<br />

2.000,00<br />

1.000,00<br />

0,00<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

landfill evolution<br />

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005<br />

landfill industrial waste landfill household waste


Figure 54-3: Evolution in Landfill <strong>of</strong> Household and Industrial <strong>Waste</strong> in Flanders<br />

kton<br />

804<br />

7000<br />

6000<br />

5000<br />

4000<br />

3000<br />

2000<br />

1000<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

incineration evolution<br />

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005<br />

54.5 Implementation Costs<br />

incineration industrial waste incineration household waste<br />

Landfill and incineration bans can impose the financing <strong>of</strong> more expensive waste<br />

treatment or waste recycling technologies on waste generators.<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> the landfill and incineration levy is not to finance the MINA-fund, but to<br />

steer waste to better waste treatment techniques. The revenues drop, or remain<br />

stable, even when each year, higher tariffs are used (see Figure 54-4).<br />

54.6 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

In Germany, landfill bans have been imposed with a clearly marked transition period<br />

between publication in the state courier and entry into force. This has created some<br />

adverse effects with landfills that have tried to use all remaining permitted capacity,<br />

but in general it has stirred the waste treatment industry to develop and install<br />

alternative waste treatment facilities.<br />

In Flanders, the landfill and incineration bans entered into force from the moment<br />

they were published, but the implementing mechanism allowed for individual<br />

exemptions as well. The effect is that industry has focused on addressing these<br />

exemptions, based on capacity problems, rather than on installing new technologies.


Figure 54-4: Revenues from Flemish Levies on Landfill and Incineration<br />

milieon euro<br />

805<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

79,3<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

revenues levies on landfill an incineration<br />

66,8<br />

53,7<br />

41<br />

38<br />

40<br />

40,7<br />

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007<br />

54.7 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

No social or distributional consequences have been observed under the latest version<br />

on the legislation (see Section 54.10). However, it might be expected that the levy<br />

does affect some industrial sectors more than others, notably those which would, in<br />

the absence <strong>of</strong> the levy, tend to be more reliant on landfilling.<br />

Some municipalities which host large landfills or incinerators that serve a whole<br />

region can benefit from the revenue derived from the levies, which can become an<br />

important source <strong>of</strong> income for the municipal administration. The effect can be an<br />

eagerness to host these kinds <strong>of</strong> installations.<br />

54.8 Complementary Policies<br />

Levies on waste disposal can only be effective in terms <strong>of</strong> their environmental effects<br />

if alternative management routes are available through recycling or prevention. Levies<br />

should, therefore, be accompanied by instruments promoting, or enhancing, recycling<br />

and prevention.<br />

The policy is complementary to other environmental levies, <strong>of</strong> which the most<br />

important is a levy on wastewater.<br />

An essential complementary policy is the MINA-fund, where the revenues are<br />

combined with other revenues from different environmental levies. The levies gain<br />

public acceptance if the revenues are used for environmental policies. The MINA-fund<br />

is used to support the project arm <strong>of</strong> OVAM and the other environment<br />

administrations.


54.9 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The waste levies are intended to be regulating, which means that the polluter should<br />

pay and, as a result, be motivated to prevent or recycle his / her waste. When<br />

payment <strong>of</strong> a levy can be recovered through use <strong>of</strong> tax allowances, the incentive<br />

effect disappears, and society carries the costs <strong>of</strong> the levy. Flemish law has recently<br />

been adapted to prohibit levies being deducted from corporation tax as company<br />

expenditures.<br />

As companies cannot recover their levies via their tax declaration, an inequality has<br />

risen between private companies and intermunicipal utility companies, since the<br />

latter do not have to pay taxes. Therefore the Flemish government has introduced a<br />

provision whereby companies that have to pay taxes can diminish their levies by a<br />

factor <strong>of</strong> 0.7.<br />

The main argument introduced by OVAM is an alignment between companies subject<br />

to corporate taxes and associations which are not. The compensation with factor 0.7<br />

intends to create equality between market rates applied by intermunicipal operators<br />

and by private operators.<br />

In order to compensate for the non tax deductible costs, a private operator will charge<br />

the waste producer a more expensive price (corresponding to the corporation tax that<br />

has to be paid). <strong>Waste</strong> companies state that their prices are increased by a factor<br />

1.51 as a result <strong>of</strong> the inequality. For each €100 <strong>of</strong> disposal levy, the operator will<br />

charge a waste producer €151. In this way he was suffering a competitive<br />

disadvantage relative to an intermunicipal utility company that can charge €100 <strong>of</strong><br />

levy as €100 to be paid by the producer.<br />

Now, private operators can diminish their levies by a factor 0.7. Instead <strong>of</strong> €100, they<br />

pay only €70 to government. They charge the waste producer, however, €70<br />

multiplied by 1.51, which is comparable to the €100 paid by the intermunicipality<br />

(slightly higher at 70 x 1.51 = 105).<br />

54.10 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

For several years, waste levies were avoided by classifying wastes as sorting residues,<br />

which attract a much lower tariff. <strong>Waste</strong> lorries with mixed waste entered the sorting<br />

plant and immediately left the plant with the same load, but with waste now called<br />

“recycling residue”.<br />

To avoid this activity, percentages <strong>of</strong> what is acceptable as recycling residue have<br />

been introduced in the legislation. A perverse effect is that now, waste is mixed up<br />

until the maximum percentage <strong>of</strong> recycling residue is obtained, so that it can be<br />

landfilled or incinerated with diminished levies.<br />

The municipalities can demand surcharges on the levies for companies on their<br />

territory. It is sometimes more effective to charge levies for illegal dumping or<br />

incineration than to seek to obtain a prosecution and to seek to have a fine imposed.<br />

Levies, and surcharges, can be demanded on a quarterly basis until an illegal dump<br />

has been cleaned.<br />

806<br />

29/09/09


54.11 Lessons Learned<br />

A complex system can be very balanced and can contain a lot <strong>of</strong> measures to avoid<br />

adverse effects or unjust levies, but a complex system opens a lot <strong>of</strong> space for<br />

discussion, and many issues <strong>of</strong> interpretation. A simple system is more transparent<br />

and easier to manage and to control. The right balance between simplicity and<br />

complexity has to be found.<br />

Very high standards for the administration are necessary, as the system is susceptible<br />

to fraud, since large amounts <strong>of</strong> money are involved and interpretation issues can<br />

arise.<br />

It should not be able to <strong>of</strong>fset levies against corporate taxes, unless a choice is made<br />

for a financing contribution instead <strong>of</strong> a regulating levy.<br />

The German model for introducing a landfill ban (a strict ban with a future starting<br />

date) is more able to stir waste treatment and recycling investments than the Flemish<br />

approach with an immediate introduction and a system for exemptions.<br />

Levies can support the waste treatment hierarchy, if they serve to make landfilling<br />

more expensive than incineration, and definitely more expensive than recycling.<br />

54.12 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

The following would appear to be pre-requisites for such levies:<br />

807<br />

� Legal and fiscal know-how within the waste administration;<br />

� Enough manpower for a strict follow up, both for interpreting the levy<br />

declarations on paper and the inspection on the field; and<br />

� Political will to introduce a tax.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


55.0 Landfill Allowance Schemes (UK)<br />

55.1 Outline <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

The principle policy for ensuring that the targets under Article 5 <strong>of</strong> the Landfill<br />

Directive are met in the UK are the Landfill Allowances Schemes (LASs). The targets,<br />

and hence, the LASs, apply only to municipal waste, and so, the definition <strong>of</strong><br />

municipal waste acquires some significance.<br />

55.1.1 UK Definition <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

“Municipal waste” is defined in Article 2(b) <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive as: 1009<br />

808<br />

29/09/09<br />

“waste from households, as well as waste which, because <strong>of</strong> its nature or<br />

composition, is similar to waste from households”.<br />

When implementing the Landfill Directive, UK Government followed the ‘copyout<br />

approach’ and included a definition <strong>of</strong> ‘municipal waste’ in the <strong>Waste</strong> and Emissions<br />

Trading Act that is similar to that in the Landfill Directive: 1010<br />

“(a) waste from households, and<br />

(b) other waste that, because <strong>of</strong> its nature or composition, is similar to waste<br />

from households.”<br />

In an attempt to provide certainty and clarity through consistent interpretation the<br />

Government set out, in guidance which was the subject <strong>of</strong> repeated consultation, its<br />

view that this definition encompasses ‘all waste under the control <strong>of</strong> local<br />

authorities’. Under this interpretation it follows that any waste which passes the test<br />

<strong>of</strong> being in the possession or under the control <strong>of</strong> a waste disposal or collection<br />

authority, and so potentially within the LAS regime, also passes the test <strong>of</strong> being<br />

municipal waste, and so is within the LAS regime. It is on this interpretation that LAS<br />

has been designed and operates.<br />

55.1.2 Devolved Administrations and The Role <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal<br />

Authorities<br />

Prior to the late 1990s, the market for municipal waste services could be considered<br />

to be ‘a UK one’. Even so, within the UK, different waste management companies<br />

have their own regional strongholds, as well as their own areas <strong>of</strong> specific expertise.<br />

Since the late 1990s, the different devolved administrations have started to shape<br />

their waste management strategies in ways which are specific to their own<br />

circumstances and priorities. They have, however, been constrained in their ability to<br />

1009 Council Directive 1999/31/EC <strong>of</strong> 26 April 1999 on the landfill <strong>of</strong> waste Official Journal L 182 ,<br />

16/07/1999 P. 0001 – 0019.<br />

1010 <strong>Waste</strong> and Emissions Trading Act 2003, Part 1: <strong>Waste</strong>, 13 th November 2003.


forge a genuinely ‘autonomous’ path by virtue <strong>of</strong> the fact that some key aspects <strong>of</strong><br />

legislation – notably fiscal policy – still fall under the competence <strong>of</strong> Whitehall<br />

Government. So, for example, the different administrations could not set the Landfill<br />

Tax at the level they may have wished because Whitehall effectively controls fiscal<br />

policy. 1011<br />

The different devolved administrations have different local government structures. In<br />

England, local government responsibilities are <strong>of</strong>ten split into two tiers, those <strong>of</strong> the<br />

lower-tier (the District and Borough Councils) and those <strong>of</strong> the upper-tier (the County<br />

Councils), though in some (usually metropolitan) areas, the responsibilities are vested<br />

in one single body and they are known as Unitary Authorities. <strong>Waste</strong> collection is a<br />

responsibility <strong>of</strong> the lower-tier <strong>of</strong> local government, and these are called <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Collection Authorities (WCAs). <strong>Waste</strong> treatment and disposal, as well as operation <strong>of</strong><br />

civic amenity sites and spatial planning as it affects waste, are all responsibilities <strong>of</strong><br />

the upper tier, known as <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Authorities (WDAs). Unitary Authorities fulfil<br />

the functions <strong>of</strong> both WCA and WDA for the area they cover.<br />

The picture is complicated further in some areas, such as Greater Manchester,<br />

Merseyside and London, in that in these areas, there exist Statutory Joint <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Disposal Authorities (SJWDAs), which are not local authorities in the conventional<br />

sense (their only raison d’etre is to deal with waste matters), but which take on most<br />

<strong>of</strong> the responsibilities <strong>of</strong> the upper tier <strong>of</strong> local government as regards waste in those<br />

areas they cover.<br />

This rather complex system <strong>of</strong> local government organisation is not replicated in<br />

Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland. All local authorities are unitary in these<br />

administrations. In principle, this should imply that decision making in these<br />

administrations is more streamlined.<br />

In summary, regarding local government structures, and with particular emphasis on<br />

the responsibility for waste disposal:<br />

809<br />

� In England, there are 394 local authorities. As regards waste disposal matters,<br />

there are 121 waste disposal authorities (including SJWDAs). Some <strong>of</strong> the 121<br />

authorities are, where residual waste is concerned, working in partnerships <strong>of</strong><br />

more than one WDA;<br />

� In Wales, there are 22 Unitary Authorities. The Welsh authorities are also<br />

forming groupings. We believe there are currently 9 ‘groupings’, though there<br />

is still some movement among these;<br />

1011 Scotland and Wales, for example, have lamented the slow pace at which the tax has increased, as<br />

well as the fact that they have no control over the use <strong>of</strong> the revenue raised. Scotland and Wales are<br />

also covered by the Environmental Protection Act 1990 (and subsequent amendments) which<br />

effectively prevents local authorities from charging households directly for waste. These are two key<br />

policies which, taken in combination, would have been sufficient to drive recycling rates higher and<br />

faster over the recent past.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


810<br />

� In Scotland, there are 31 Unitary Authorities. For the purposes <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management, these 31 authorities formed groupings known as <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy<br />

Areas, <strong>of</strong> which there are 11;<br />

� In Northern Ireland, there are 26 unitary authorities. These have formed 3<br />

Groupings for the purposes <strong>of</strong> waste management. However, it should be<br />

noted that now that the Northern Ireland Assembly is ‘active’ (after many years<br />

in suspended animation), a fairly major restructuring <strong>of</strong> local government is<br />

being considered, the proposed outcome <strong>of</strong> which is consolidation <strong>of</strong> areas<br />

which are not consistent with the borders <strong>of</strong> the Regions working together on<br />

planning for municipal waste.<br />

As far as waste disposal is concerned, therefore, across the UK, one could say that<br />

there are something <strong>of</strong> the order 200 WDAs.<br />

55.1.3 Basics <strong>of</strong> the LASs<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> and Emissions Trading Act 2003 essentially transposes the Landfill<br />

Directive into UK law, and was granted Royal Assent on 13 November 2003. 1012 The<br />

legislation gives the Secretary <strong>of</strong> State powers to impose a duty upon WDAs to ensure<br />

that they landfill no more biodegradable municipal waste than that for which they<br />

hold the equivalent number <strong>of</strong> landfill allowances.<br />

Within the UK, the different devolved administrations have each adopted an approach<br />

to meeting the Article 5 Landfill Directive targets which makes use <strong>of</strong> the allocation,<br />

to local authorities, <strong>of</strong> a diminishing (over time) number <strong>of</strong> allowances for the disposal<br />

<strong>of</strong> biodegradable municipal waste to landfill. Biodegradable municipal waste (BMW)<br />

has to be dealt with in ways other than landfill in line with the overall allocation <strong>of</strong><br />

allowances, with key target years being 2009/10, 2012/13 and 2019/20.<br />

The details <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Allowances Schemes (LASs) in the different countries are<br />

not the same (see Table 55-1). Notably, England and Scotland allow trading <strong>of</strong><br />

allowances (hence, in England, the scheme is known as the Landfill Allowances<br />

Trading Scheme, or LATS), whilst Wales and Northern Ireland do not. In addition, for<br />

the purposes <strong>of</strong> making mass balance calculations, the biodegradable content <strong>of</strong><br />

waste is assumed to be different in the different countries. 1013 Finally, as a point <strong>of</strong><br />

technical detail, the quantity <strong>of</strong> BMW landfilled can be reduced either through<br />

sending less material to landfill or through reducing the biodegradability <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

which is landfilled. The approach to measuring loss in biodegradability is different in<br />

Scotland to the approach in the other administrations <strong>of</strong> the UK.<br />

It is clearly a simplification to believe that all local authorities will have similar waste<br />

composition. Indeed, the fact that the composition <strong>of</strong> waste in the different devolved<br />

1012 <strong>Waste</strong> and Emissions Trading Act 2003, Part 1: <strong>Waste</strong>, 13 th November 2003.<br />

1013 Work is ongoing in Defra to estimate the current biodegradable content <strong>of</strong> waste in England, and a<br />

review has also taken place in Northern Ireland. Our understanding is that latest estimates suggest a<br />

downward shift in biodegradable content in both areas. We are not, however, able to make use <strong>of</strong> this<br />

data at this stage as it is not in the public domain.<br />

29/09/09


administrations is deemed to change as one crosses borders between the countries<br />

<strong>of</strong> the UK highlights a peculiarity <strong>of</strong> the approach this is. It is well known that<br />

(amongst other things) differences in housing types, and differences in<br />

socioeconomic standing will influence the composition <strong>of</strong> household waste.<br />

Another factor which will influence composition is the nature and quantity <strong>of</strong><br />

commercial waste collected as municipal waste in any WDA area. Whether this is<br />

collected at household waste recycling centres (HWRCs) or at commercial premises<br />

on collection rounds is likely to determine how much <strong>of</strong> the non-household waste is,<br />

for example, inert rubble or biodegradable paper.<br />

Table 55-1: A Comparative Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Allowance Schemes in England,<br />

Wales, Scotland and Northern Ireland<br />

Name Name <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

the<br />

Scheme<br />

Scheme<br />

Biodegradable<br />

Biodegradable<br />

content content content <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

municipal municipal municipal waste waste<br />

waste<br />

Introduction<br />

Introduction Introduction <strong>of</strong><br />

the the scheme<br />

scheme<br />

Trading Trading <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

allowances<br />

allowances<br />

The The Landfill<br />

Landfill<br />

Directive Directive targets<br />

targets<br />

for for each each <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

the<br />

countries<br />

countries<br />

(tonnes (tonnes <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

biodegradable<br />

biodegradable<br />

biodegradable<br />

municipal<br />

municipal<br />

waste)<br />

waste)<br />

811<br />

England England Wales Wales<br />

Scotland Scotland Northern Northern Ireland<br />

Ireland<br />

Landfill<br />

Allowance<br />

Trading Scheme<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Landfill<br />

Allowances<br />

Scheme<br />

Landfill<br />

Allowances<br />

Scheme<br />

68% 61% 63% 71%<br />

Landfill<br />

Allowances<br />

Scheme<br />

1 April 2005 1 October 2004 1 April 2005 1 April 2005<br />

Trading is<br />

permitted<br />

although not<br />

obligatory.<br />

2009/10 2009/10 2009/10 –<br />

11,200,000<br />

2012/13 2012/13 2012/13 – 7,<br />

460,000<br />

2019/20 2019/20 2019/20 –<br />

5,220,000<br />

Sanctions Sanctions £150 per tonne<br />

excess BMW<br />

landfilled<br />

No trading <strong>of</strong><br />

allowances<br />

2009/10 2009/10 –<br />

710,000<br />

2012/13 2012/13 –<br />

470,000<br />

2019/20 2019/20 –<br />

330,000<br />

£200 per tonne<br />

excess BMW<br />

landfilled<br />

Trading will be<br />

permitted from<br />

2008. Before<br />

2008, waste<br />

disposal<br />

authorities may<br />

be able to swap<br />

allowances, at<br />

the discretion <strong>of</strong><br />

the Executive.<br />

2009/10 2009/10 –<br />

1,320,000<br />

2012/13 2012/13 –<br />

880,000<br />

2019/20 2019/20 –<br />

620,000<br />

£150 per tonne<br />

excess BMW<br />

landfilled<br />

No trading <strong>of</strong><br />

allowances.<br />

Transfer <strong>of</strong><br />

allowances<br />

between<br />

authorities<br />

permitted.<br />

2009/10 2009/10 –<br />

470, 000<br />

2012/13 2012/13 –<br />

320, 000<br />

2019/20 2019/20 –<br />

220,000<br />

£150 per tonne<br />

excess BMW<br />

landfilled<br />

Source: Defra (http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/waste/localauth/lats/pdf/latscomparanalysis.pdf)<br />

The quantity <strong>of</strong> commercial waste collected itself is affected by strategic and policy<br />

decisions made by WCAs and WDAs. As such, the grandfathering <strong>of</strong> allowances (i.e.


their allocation based on past quantities collected) is likely to imply the awarding <strong>of</strong><br />

assets to those who may have made strategic decisions in the past to maximize<br />

commercial waste collection as a revenue-raising activity for their Direct Service<br />

Organisations (DSOs). The only way to limit the degree to which the value <strong>of</strong> these<br />

assets can be realized without taking any effective action is to seek to restrict the<br />

degree to which the proportion <strong>of</strong> non-household waste collected in municipal waste<br />

can change over time.<br />

Defra has tried to clarify the way in which non-household waste is to be dealt with by<br />

local authorities. Specifically, it has sought to restrict the degree to which local<br />

authorities can reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> commercial waste they collect by providing<br />

clarification <strong>of</strong> its interpretation <strong>of</strong> Section 45(1) <strong>of</strong> the Environmental Protection Act<br />

1990. 1014 However, would-be commercial waste customers choosing, in possession <strong>of</strong><br />

all the facts, a lower cost service than one on <strong>of</strong>fer from a given local authority could<br />

not be restrained from making such a choice. It would be difficult to argue that such<br />

waste would remain ‘under the control <strong>of</strong>’ the local authority concerned where it is no<br />

longer chosen as the collection contractor.<br />

It can be seen that both the allocation mechanism and the way in which the<br />

biodegradable content <strong>of</strong> landfilled waste is calculated are likely to lead to some<br />

perverse strategies being developed, notwithstanding Defra’s move to try to head <strong>of</strong>f<br />

actions by local authorities intending to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> commercial waste they<br />

collect. It is doubtful whether Defra could really require local authorities to continue to<br />

collect commercial waste from their existing customers, and the recent court<br />

judgement in the case <strong>of</strong> WRWA v Wandsworth would tend to support this view. 1015<br />

The additional risk that this would imply in respect <strong>of</strong> maintaining a balance <strong>of</strong><br />

allowances sufficient to cover the quantity <strong>of</strong> BMW being landfilled could itself be<br />

argued as justifying an increase in the price <strong>of</strong> the service being <strong>of</strong>fered by the local<br />

authority. Since competitors in the market for the provision <strong>of</strong> commercial waste<br />

collections in the WDA area would not be faced with any such risk (the waste would<br />

not fall under the definition ‘municipal’), then this would be tantamount to forcing<br />

customers to choose a higher priced service, thereby restraining trade. 1016<br />

1014 Defra (2004) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>, Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> and the Landfill Allowances Trading Scheme,<br />

http://www.defra.gov.uk/ENVIRONMENT/waste/localauth/lats/pdf/lats-municipalwastedefine.pdf.<br />

1015 In this judgement, Justice Evans-Lombe ruled that WRWA, which sought judicial review <strong>of</strong> a<br />

decision made by Wandsworth BC to set charges for trade waste which effectively reduced the quantity<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste collected by the authority, had no case for such a review. In other words, Wandsworth had not<br />

acted outside the law in essentially seeking to reduce its collection <strong>of</strong> non-household municipal waste..<br />

1016 Matters would, or course, have looked somewhat different had Defra taken the view that municipal<br />

waste did in fact include all commercial waste in the WDA area, irrespective <strong>of</strong> who collected it. This<br />

would have made the tasks <strong>of</strong> data acquisition and verification more difficult, but it would also have<br />

led, potentially, to a more rational form <strong>of</strong> collection logistics rather than encouraging its<br />

fragmentation. It might also have ensured a more enlightened approach to procurement <strong>of</strong> facilities in<br />

which treatment facilities were designed to deal not only with the material collected by the WCAs /<br />

WDAs, but also with the wider commercial wastes.<br />

812<br />

29/09/09


The desire to improve recycling performance on the part <strong>of</strong> WCAs is over-shadowed by<br />

the desire <strong>of</strong> WDAs to ensure that they comply with the terms <strong>of</strong> the Landfill<br />

Allowances Scheme under which they are operating. This relates to the mechanisms<br />

for implementing sanctions. These exist for the LASs (in the form <strong>of</strong> fines), but not for<br />

the recycling targets, though the administrations apply mechanisms which make<br />

achieving recycling targets likely to draw in additional funding from central<br />

government.<br />

55.2 Timetable<br />

The underpinning work for the LAS was a review <strong>of</strong> policy options carried out for Defra<br />

in 1999. 1017 This led to the issuing <strong>of</strong> a consultation document in the same year,<br />

Limiting Landfill, which set out policy options for compliance with the Landfill<br />

Directive, responses to which favoured a scheme similar to the one which<br />

subsequently emerged. 1018 A further consultation was carried out in 2001. 1019<br />

However, although it was widely accepted that the scheme would enter into force,<br />

details were not agreed until 2004. The <strong>Waste</strong> and Emissions Trading Act (2003) was<br />

given further substance by the Landfill Allowances and Trading Scheme (England)<br />

Regulations 2004, and similar documents (listed below) for the other devolved<br />

administrations, these having been consulted upon in the countries concerned.<br />

813<br />

� The Landfill Allowances Scheme (Scotland) Regulations 2005<br />

� The Landfill Allowances Scheme (Wales) Regulations 2004<br />

� The Landfill Allowances Scheme (Northern Ireland) Regulations 2004<br />

The LASs ‘went live’ on April 1 2005.<br />

55.3 Key Organisations Involved in Implementation and<br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The principal players are:<br />

� The WDAs themselves;<br />

� The regulators (the Environment Agency, SEPA and the Environment and the<br />

Northern Ireland Environment Agency), who act as auditors for the scheme,<br />

reviewing data and the balances <strong>of</strong> allowances held by WDAs; and<br />

� Defra, the Scottish Executive, the Welsh Assembly Government, and the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment Northern Ireland, who are the allocating<br />

authorities in their respective countries.<br />

1017 D. Hogg (1999) <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments to Implement the Proposed Landfill Directive BMSW Targets,<br />

Final Report to DETR.<br />

1018 DETR (1999) Limiting Landfill, October 1999, London: HMSO. Devolved administrations carried<br />

out similar consultations.<br />

1019 DETR (2001) Tradable Landfill Permits Consultation Paper, March 2001, London: HMSO.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


55.4 Pre-implementation / Evaluation Studies Available<br />

There were some studies which sought to understand the potential impact <strong>of</strong> the<br />

LASs. One sought to outline potential instruments. 1020 Another study sought to<br />

understand the interaction between the allowances system and the landfill tax. 1021<br />

However, both <strong>of</strong> these focused upon the mechanisms rather than the expected<br />

outcomes from the schemes.<br />

55.5 Environmental Benefits<br />

The environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> LASs are somewhat difficult to discern. In truth, the<br />

effects appear to be varying by devolved administration, though this masks the<br />

underlying activities which are leading to preparation for procurement <strong>of</strong><br />

infrastructure. The following comments examine the situation in each <strong>of</strong> the devolved<br />

administrations. However, these comments are contextualised by some crucial points:<br />

814<br />

� The path to reducing landfilled BMW under a time constraint is achieved most<br />

quickly through improving collection systems; and<br />

� Procuring and commissioning infrastructure for treating residual waste has<br />

been slow, partly owing to the nature <strong>of</strong> the procurement process, and partly<br />

owing to the nature <strong>of</strong> what is being procured.<br />

Hence, in the short-term, many authorities have focused upon recycling and<br />

composting, recognising the time taken to procure residual waste treatment<br />

infrastructure.<br />

55.5.1 England<br />

In England, the LASs have been crucial in focussing the minds <strong>of</strong> local authorities on<br />

their obligations to deliver the Landfill Directive targets. <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy for England<br />

2007 increased recycling targets for household waste, partly in recognition <strong>of</strong> the fact<br />

that the pace <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment was not sufficient to ensure Landfill<br />

Directive targets would be met, and partly in recognition <strong>of</strong> the climate change<br />

benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling.<br />

Table 55-2 shows how landfilled BMW has declined in the UK over the first full years<br />

<strong>of</strong> audited data. A 7% decrease in BMW landfilled was followed by an 8% decrease in<br />

2007/8, so that in 2007/08, England landfilled 85 per cent <strong>of</strong> the BMW landfilled in<br />

the first scheme year.<br />

1020 D. Hogg (1999) <strong>Policy</strong> Instruments to Implement the Proposed Landfill Directive BMSW Targets,<br />

Final Report to DETR.<br />

1021 D. Hogg and R. Salmons (1999) Instruments to Implement the Proposed Landfill Directive BMSW<br />

Targets, Final Report to DETR.<br />

29/09/09


Table 55-2: BMW Landfilled in England<br />

815<br />

Year Year BMW BMW BMW landfilled landfilled (tonnes) (tonnes) Percentage Percentage <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> previous previous year’s year’s year’s BMW BMW BMW landfilled<br />

landfilled<br />

2007/08 10,581,953 92<br />

2006/07 11,548,213 93<br />

2005/06 12,380,966 Not applicable<br />

Source: Environment Agency (2008) Report on the Landfill Allowances and Trading<br />

Scheme 2007/08, November 2008<br />

In England, the recycling rate for household waste has continued to increase over<br />

time, but so has the proportion <strong>of</strong> waste dealt with through incineration and MBT.<br />

The effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the scheme might also be considered through assessment <strong>of</strong><br />

prices for landfill allowances in future years. The trading scheme allows for forward<br />

buying and selling <strong>of</strong> allowances. Currently, for what many thought would be a crunch<br />

year in 2012/13 (the second target year), allowances are being traded well below the<br />

level <strong>of</strong> fines (£150 per tonne) at around £15-£20 per tonne. Logically, now that it is<br />

known that landfill tax will increase to £72 per tonne, the price <strong>of</strong> landfill allowances<br />

ought to be rather small since this should reflect, in the equilibrium situation, the<br />

difference between the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling and the costs <strong>of</strong> the marginal treatment<br />

option for reducing BMW landfilled.<br />

55.5.2 Wales<br />

In Wales, the development <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment has been somewhat slow.<br />

Notwithstanding this, the Welsh assembly Government is developing a waste strategy<br />

which is intended to ensure that the 2013 Landfill Directive targets can be met<br />

principally through source separation, with a target <strong>of</strong> 70% recycling being set (63%<br />

through source separation, 7% from recycling <strong>of</strong> residual waste and treatment<br />

residues).<br />

The following information comes from the Environment Agency. 1022 Thus far, the<br />

strategy is working. All 22 local authorities in Wales achieved their 2007/8 allowance<br />

obligations. In 2007/8, Welsh local authorities sent 680,9121 tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

biodegradable municipal waste (BMW) to landfill compared to the 2007/8 allowance<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> 866,000 tonnes (or 21% less BMW was landfilled in Wales relative to<br />

the allowance allocation).<br />

91% <strong>of</strong> local authorities in 2007/8 reduced the actual amount <strong>of</strong> BMW sent to landfill<br />

compared to 2006/7. Two local authorities sent more BMW to landfill than in<br />

2006/7, these being Ceredigion and Flintshire. Over the three years to 2007/8,<br />

Wales reduced the amount <strong>of</strong> BMW sent to landfill by 20%, or 170,577 tonnes<br />

1022 Environment Agency (2008) Report on the Landfill Allowances Scheme (Wales) 2007/08,<br />

September 2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


compared to the amount landfilled in 2005/6. Wales is currently landfilling 4% less<br />

BMW (29,088 tonnes) than it is required to under the first Landfill Directive reporting<br />

year in 2009/10.<br />

Procurement Hubs have now been established in Wales with the intention <strong>of</strong><br />

procuring both facilities for the anaerobic digestion <strong>of</strong> separately collected food waste<br />

and the treatment <strong>of</strong> residual waste. Under the new Welsh Strategy, local authorities<br />

will be required to collect food waste separately. 1023 The Welsh Assembly Government<br />

is supporting these procurement efforts.<br />

55.5.3 Northern Ireland<br />

Between 2005/06 and 2007/08, there was a decline <strong>of</strong> 8.57% in BMW landfilled. 1024<br />

Municipal waste arisings decreased by 0.28% between 2006/07 and 2007/08,<br />

whilst the municipal waste recycling rate increased from 25.54% to 28.48%. If BMW<br />

landfilled remained constant at 2007/8 levels, Northern Ireland as a whole in<br />

2009/10 would have a deficit <strong>of</strong> allowances <strong>of</strong> 40,205 tonnes.<br />

However, the reduction in BMW sent to landfill should continue to decrease as the<br />

three waste management groups continue to implement their <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Plans.<br />

55.5.4 Scotland<br />

In Scotland, landfilled BMW has fallen steadily over time. The BMW landfilled in<br />

2007/08 was 79% the level <strong>of</strong> 2004/05. The quantity incinerated had remained<br />

more or less constant. Total MSW was relatively static, but the recycling rate<br />

increased from 17% to 31% (see Table 55-3).<br />

Table 55-3: Evolution <strong>of</strong> Recycling and Landfill in Scotland<br />

MSW MSW MSW Landfilled Landfilled Incinerated<br />

Incinerated<br />

Recycled Recycled Recycled / /<br />

/<br />

Composted Composted<br />

Composted<br />

BMW BMW<br />

BMW<br />

Landfilled Landfilled<br />

Landfilled<br />

BMW<br />

BMW<br />

Landfilled<br />

Landfilled<br />

as as % %<br />

%<br />

2004/05<br />

2004/05<br />

2004/05 3,407,978 2,748,819 71,548 588,039 1,724,273<br />

2005/06 3,415,594 2,504,085 77,844 833,679 1,541,557 89%<br />

2006/07 3,437,046 2,398,433 60,947 977,655 1,471,026 85%<br />

2007/08 3,413,701 2,256,661 74,603 1,082,438 1,369,614 79%<br />

Source: SEPA Landfill Allowance Scheme Reports<br />

1023 This followed analysis <strong>of</strong> the financial case for doing so – see Eunomia (2008) Scoping New<br />

Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Targets for Wales, Report for the Welsh Local Government Association and the Welsh<br />

Assembly Government.<br />

1024 Northern Ireland Environment Agency (2008) The Landfill Allowance Scheme Regulations (2004)<br />

Northern Ireland (NILAS) 2007/08 Annual Report, October 2008.<br />

816<br />

29/09/09


55.6 Implementation Costs<br />

The intention <strong>of</strong> the England scheme – involving trading – was to enable a target for<br />

landfilling BMW to be met at least cost to the country. Clearly, costs have been<br />

incurred in administering the scheme, but as a mechanism for meeting the Landfill<br />

Directive, the scheme appears to have been quite successful thus far. Other<br />

institutional factors in UK waste management are making compliance poorer value,<br />

and there is a suggestion that in residual waste procurements, bidders are increasing<br />

prices in the expectation that local authorities will accept these bids because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> exposure to landfill allowance deficits or fines.<br />

55.7 Effects on Technical Change / Innovation<br />

Our experience <strong>of</strong> working with local authorities is that the LASs are clearly<br />

influencing the pace <strong>of</strong> development <strong>of</strong> recycling and composting, and are focusing<br />

local authority minds on developing residual waste treatment facilities. Efforts to<br />

reduce waste are also being heightened in some authorities.<br />

Equally, the LASs are making authorities more commercially aware.<br />

It is interesting to note that the LASs effects in terms <strong>of</strong> the delivery <strong>of</strong> residual waste<br />

treatment infrastructure has been less apparent than the flurry <strong>of</strong> activity to engage in<br />

procurement processes. One reason for this is the lengthy period taken to deliver<br />

waste facilities, particularly those <strong>of</strong> more capital intense nature, and those which<br />

have proved more contentious at the siting stage. Indeed, some commentators<br />

suggest there is still a possibility that the UK may not meet its targets for 2013, but<br />

that it might be tending towards over-capacity in the medium- to long-term. This is<br />

because the lead-times are long, and, some have argued, the process <strong>of</strong> developing<br />

facilities should have begun much sooner:<br />

817<br />

The EU Directive in 1999 created a need for a strategy for significantly<br />

increasing diversion <strong>of</strong> waste away from landfill. Before 2003 the<br />

<strong>Department</strong>’s strategies lacked practical plans for reducing reliance on<br />

landfill. Only then did the <strong>Department</strong> start to address the complex issues<br />

involved in building new waste treatment infrastructure. As a result, the<br />

market for waste infrastructure projects developed slowly. Only two <strong>of</strong> the new<br />

waste infrastructure projects developed since the EU Directive (1999) have<br />

completed construction <strong>of</strong> all planned assets. 1025<br />

Equally, it might be argued that the choice <strong>of</strong> facility and the approach to<br />

procurement has tended to lengthen lead-times rather than shorten them. The NAO’s<br />

review lends some support to this view:<br />

Prior to contract award, PFI projects have been delayed by an average <strong>of</strong> 19<br />

months compared to the original timetables. Some delays occur because<br />

projects need to improve their business cases to gain central government<br />

1025 NAO (2009) Managing the PFI <strong>Waste</strong> Programme, Report by the Comptroller and Auditor General,<br />

HC 66 Session 2008-2009, 14 January 2009.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


818<br />

29/09/09<br />

approval. The current difficulties in the financing markets are also delaying<br />

large deals. Some projects have, however, been funded by contractors out <strong>of</strong><br />

existing financial resources giving the prospect <strong>of</strong> faster deal closure. After<br />

contract award, delays have occurred because some projects have<br />

encountered difficulty in obtaining planning permission. 1026<br />

55.8 Social and Distributional Consequences<br />

There are no obvious consequences <strong>of</strong> this nature other than those which would flow<br />

from Landfill Directive implementation. To the extent that authorities have had to<br />

make allowance purchases thus far, these have been at low prices, implying costs per<br />

annum <strong>of</strong> the order €1 per household per annum, and less, thus far.<br />

55.9 Complementary Policies<br />

The landfill tax has operated alongside the LASs. However, local authorities might<br />

argue that the tax does not operate as a ‘complementary’ policy, but rather, that it<br />

overlaps.<br />

Recycling targets have been broadly complementary to the LASs to the extent that<br />

where recycling increases, frequently, some or all <strong>of</strong> the additional material targeted<br />

for collection is biodegradable (paper, card, food waste, garden waste, textiles, etc.).<br />

Regulations have also been passed to enable assessment <strong>of</strong> the loss in<br />

biodegradability achieved by biological treatment plants.<br />

55.10 Effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> on Pricing <strong>of</strong> Resources / Services<br />

The LASs have an effect on the infra-marginal tonnages <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste which<br />

is to be landfilled (i.e. the tonnages above the amount for which allowances are held).<br />

The effect is to increase the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling these infra-marginal tonnes. However,<br />

the increase in cost is determined by the demand for allowances where allowances<br />

are tradable (as in England), and by the level <strong>of</strong> fines where trading is prohibited (as,<br />

for example, in Wales).<br />

The effect <strong>of</strong> this on the behaviour <strong>of</strong> local authorities has been significant. Indeed,<br />

although it was widely anticipated (since 1999) that a scheme such as the LASs<br />

would be introduced, many local authorities’ waste <strong>of</strong>ficers found it difficult to make<br />

the case for investing in new services and infrastructure to meet their obligations until<br />

it became clear that a sanction, in the form <strong>of</strong> fines, would be applied in the event <strong>of</strong><br />

failure to discharge obligations under the scheme. This enabled waste <strong>of</strong>ficers to<br />

make the case to finance <strong>of</strong>ficers and Chief Executives <strong>of</strong> their local authority along<br />

the lines that failure to improve services could trigger significant financial penalties.<br />

The magnitude <strong>of</strong> the fines - £150 per tonne <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste landfilled for<br />

which no allowance is held (and £200 per tonne in Wales) – is highly significant in the<br />

1026 NAO (2009) Managing the PFI <strong>Waste</strong> Programme, Report by the Comptroller and Auditor General,<br />

HC 66 Session 2008-2009, 14 January 2009.


context <strong>of</strong> UK waste management where landfill gate fees are <strong>of</strong> the order £20 per<br />

tonne before landfill tax, with tax currently (in April 2009) at £40 per tonne. The<br />

business case for dealing with waste in ways other than landfilling has been<br />

considerably strengthened by the prospect <strong>of</strong> fines, or the need to purchase<br />

allowances at a relatively high cost.<br />

Interestingly, however, although many local authorities developed business cases on<br />

the basis that fines could be triggered, in England, where trading is allowed, the value<br />

at which allowances have been traded has been rather low. This was to be expected<br />

in early years since WDAs’ allocation <strong>of</strong> allowances were based on a system <strong>of</strong><br />

grandfathering, with allowances issued tapering towards a fixed share <strong>of</strong> the UK<br />

quota <strong>of</strong> allowances for the first target year, 2009/10 (the UK has availed itself <strong>of</strong> the<br />

four-year derogation, available to those countries who were landfilling more than 80%<br />

<strong>of</strong> their municipal waste in 1995).<br />

In target years, and one year immediately before and after each target year, the<br />

freedom to bank and borrow allowances is completely, and partially restricted,<br />

respectively. This means that from 2009/10 to 2012/13, there is limited potential to<br />

bank and borrow allowances, moving the allowance market into a ‘clearing’ situation.<br />

Many commentators expect allowance values to increase as a result <strong>of</strong> supply being<br />

much tighter, and demand for allowances increasing. Even so, forward purchases <strong>of</strong><br />

allowances are beginning to occur for those years, and prices for allowances <strong>of</strong><br />

between £12-£25 are being <strong>of</strong>fered.<br />

This suggests that, as with many other allowance trading schemes, the traded value<br />

<strong>of</strong> allowances may be lower than commentators have expected. However, it remains<br />

too early to say how the market will look in 2012/13, with recent commentators still<br />

suggesting a shortfall is possibly, and indeed, likely.<br />

55.11 Evasion and Enforcement<br />

The Environment Agency has audited data from WDAs and has commented upon the<br />

issues which are arising in terms <strong>of</strong> reporting <strong>of</strong> data. 1027 They report on data as<br />

received, and some comments are picked up below, but a more general issues with<br />

the scheme is the way in which it has led to shift in waste across administrative<br />

categories, from ‘municipal’ waste into commercial waste, though local authorities<br />

withdrawing from the provision <strong>of</strong> collection services for commercial waste.<br />

Defra has tried to clarify the way in which non-household waste is to be dealt with by<br />

local authorities. Specifically, it has sought to restrict the degree to which local<br />

authorities can reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> commercial waste they collect by providing<br />

clarification <strong>of</strong> its interpretation <strong>of</strong> Section 45(1) <strong>of</strong> the Environmental Protection Act<br />

1990. 1028 However, would-be commercial waste customers choosing, in possession <strong>of</strong><br />

1027 Environment Agency (2008) Report on the Landfill Allowances and Trading Scheme 2007/08,<br />

November 2008.<br />

1028 Defra (2004) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>, Commercial <strong>Waste</strong> and the Landfill Allowances Trading Scheme,<br />

http://www.defra.gov.uk/ENVIRONMENT/waste/localauth/lats/pdf/lats-municipalwastedefine.pdf.<br />

819<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


all the facts, a lower cost service than one on <strong>of</strong>fer from a given local authority could<br />

not be restrained from making such a choice. It would be difficult to argue that such<br />

waste would remain ‘under the control <strong>of</strong>’ the local authority concerned where it is no<br />

longer chosen as the collection contractor.<br />

It can be seen that both the allocation mechanism and the way in which the<br />

biodegradable content <strong>of</strong> landfilled waste is calculated are likely to lead to some<br />

perverse strategies being developed, notwithstanding Defra’s move to try to head <strong>of</strong>f<br />

actions by local authorities intending to reduce the amount <strong>of</strong> commercial waste they<br />

collect. It is doubtful whether Defra could really require local authorities to continue to<br />

collect commercial waste from their existing customers, and a court judgement in the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> WRWA v Wandsworth would tend to support this view. 1029 The additional risk<br />

that this would imply in respect <strong>of</strong> maintaining a balance <strong>of</strong> allowances sufficient to<br />

cover the quantity <strong>of</strong> BMW being landfilled could itself be argued as justifying an<br />

increase in the price <strong>of</strong> the service being <strong>of</strong>fered by the local authority. Since<br />

competitors in the market for the provision <strong>of</strong> commercial waste collections in the<br />

WDA area would not be faced with any such risk (the waste would not fall under the<br />

definition ‘municipal’), then this would be tantamount to forcing customers to choose<br />

a higher priced service, thereby restraining trade. 1030<br />

Although one cannot be sure that changes in the rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> municipal waste at<br />

a national level are occurring at the expense <strong>of</strong> an increase in the rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong><br />

commercial waste (because the quality <strong>of</strong> data on commercial waste does not such<br />

an analysis to be undertaken), the simple fact is that Eunomia is well aware that this<br />

happening on a wide scale.<br />

In addition to the above points, the reporting <strong>of</strong> data by local authorities clearly leaves<br />

something to be desired. The Environment Agency noted that several local authorities<br />

send material to be recycled to brokers, intermediaries and reprocessors. Sometimes<br />

the waste is reprocessed and recovered in the UK and at other times it is exported.<br />

The Agency noted that local authorities differ in their attention to detail when<br />

reporting the final destination <strong>of</strong> municipal waste, yet this information is required in<br />

order to demonstrate that reprocessing and recovery is legitimate and has diverted<br />

waste from landfill. 1031<br />

1029 In this judgement, Justice Evans-Lombe ruled that WRWA, which sought judicial review <strong>of</strong> a<br />

decision made by Wandsworth BC to set charges for trade waste which effectively reduced the quantity<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste collected by the authority, had no case for such a review. In other words, Wandsworth had not<br />

acted outside the law in essentially seeking to reduce its collection <strong>of</strong> non-household municipal waste.<br />

1030 Matters would, or course, have looked somewhat different had Defra taken the view that municipal<br />

waste did in fact include all commercial waste in the WDA area, irrespective <strong>of</strong> who collected it. This<br />

would have made the tasks <strong>of</strong> data acquisition and verification more difficult, but it would also have<br />

led, potentially, to a more rational form <strong>of</strong> collection logistics rather than encouraging its<br />

fragmentation. It might also have ensured a more enlightened approach to procurement <strong>of</strong> facilities in<br />

which treatment facilities were designed to deal not only with the material collected by the WCAs /<br />

WDAs, but also with the wider commercial wastes.<br />

1031 Environment Agency (2008) Report on the Landfill Allowances and Trading Scheme 2007/08,<br />

November 2008.<br />

820<br />

29/09/09


During 2007/08, the Environment Agency also examined MRF data and how<br />

authorities verify the information they report on the data reporting system, waste<br />

dataflow (WDF). They found that reported reject rates from MRFs varied considerably,<br />

with some authorities reporting an implausible zero percent reject rate, and cases<br />

arising where the reject rates reported by authorities using the same facility varied<br />

significantly (see Table 55-4).<br />

Table 55-4: Reject Rates Reported by Local Authorities Using MRFs<br />

821<br />

Reject Reject rates rates<br />

rates<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

No. No. <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> authorities* authorities* with<br />

with<br />

reported reported MRF rejects in<br />

this this this range range<br />

range<br />

zero reject 32<br />

Above zero less than 5 per cent 62<br />

5 per cent to less than 10 per cent 43<br />

10 per cent to less than 15 per cent 24<br />

15 per cent to less than 20 per cent 11<br />

20 per cent or more 10<br />

Source: Environment Agency (2008) Report on the Landfill Allowances and Trading Scheme 2007/08,<br />

November 2008.<br />

From 2008/09, the Environment Agency intends to serve notice on authorities that<br />

report zero reject rates, asking them for firm evidence to substantiate reporting zero<br />

reject rates (which is likely to be impossible to provide). The EA will also review reject<br />

rates which are low and inconsistent with the MRF’s own data and that <strong>of</strong> other<br />

authority users.<br />

Another consequence <strong>of</strong> the sorting <strong>of</strong> commingled materials is that it is well known<br />

that some materials sent from sorting facilities to reprocessors is rejected at the<br />

reprocessors’ gates. As part <strong>of</strong> our auditing process in 2008/09 we will build on the<br />

work already carried out during 2007/08 in this area.<br />

55.12 Lessons Learned<br />

There have been a number <strong>of</strong> lessons learned already in the relatively short lifetime<br />

<strong>of</strong> the LASs:<br />

� Sanctions have proved to be critical in ensuring that local authorities take not<br />

<strong>of</strong> the scheme. Targets are not worth setting if there is no intention to enforce<br />

them;<br />

� The approach to assessing the reduction in biodegradability achieved by MBT<br />

processes emerged late, and was confusing. The test methods used are<br />

expensive and unfamiliar. It was impossible for MBT processes to demonstrate<br />

their ability to comply with the requirements set out in tenders in early years <strong>of</strong><br />

the scheme because <strong>of</strong> the lateness and obscurity <strong>of</strong> the proposed<br />

mechanisms for assessment;


822<br />

� There are concerns that the mass balance approach encourages local<br />

authorities to collect large quantities <strong>of</strong> garden waste, and that the way the<br />

accounting process works encourages ‘waste generation’ and discourages<br />

home composting. Defra is considering the potential for incorporating an<br />

adjustment, related to home composting into the mass balance scheme.<br />

� The definition <strong>of</strong> municipal waste in the UK is clearly enabling some authorities<br />

to generate ‘assets’ from their allowance allocations, based on grandfathering,<br />

by simply ceasing trade waste collections. The initial proposal for the scheme<br />

proposed an allocation on household numbers;<br />

� Some WDAs, in areas where Government has planned for major new housing<br />

developments, have argued, not unreasonably, that their allocation <strong>of</strong><br />

allowances should reflect their changing circumstances. Defra and the other<br />

administrations are giving the matter some consideration. The initial proposal<br />

for the scheme proposed an allocation on household numbers, with<br />

adjustments made periodically on the basis <strong>of</strong> WDAs’ share <strong>of</strong> total<br />

households;<br />

� Crucially, in England, where allowances are tradable, the availability <strong>of</strong><br />

information <strong>of</strong> ‘market relevance’ has been limited. This is, perhaps, less<br />

problematic where the number and magnitude <strong>of</strong> trades is small, and when<br />

prices for allowances are understandably low. If the market tightens, however,<br />

there will be heightened concern regarding the quality <strong>of</strong> the market-relevant<br />

information, not least since local authority <strong>of</strong>ficers may be required to make<br />

substantial financial outlays through trades. It remains to be seen whether the<br />

LATS Trading Floor (and electronic trading floor) can provide this information;<br />

and<br />

� In the trading system, it may have been wiser to ensure that targets were set<br />

such that rules regarding banking and borrowing were the same in all years.<br />

The existing system effectively changes the rules in ‘target years’ (2009/10,<br />

2012/13 and 2019/20). This forces the market for allowances into a clearing<br />

situation when in other years, banking and borrowing gives flexibility. Arguably,<br />

this prevents any form <strong>of</strong> meaningful price formation for future years, reducing<br />

the efficiency and liquidity <strong>of</strong> the market for trading allowances in those future<br />

years.<br />

55.13 Prerequisites for Introduction<br />

Pre-requisites for the scheme’s introduction are:<br />

� Targets are set upon those who can reasonably be said to have responsibility<br />

for delivery against the targets;<br />

� A clear method for allocation, and for each WDA, a more or less clear schedule<br />

<strong>of</strong> allowances over time;<br />

� Clear rules around trading, banking and borrowing;<br />

� Crucially, sanctions to support the drive to meet targets;<br />

� Clarity about the way the WDAs’ performance would be assessed under the<br />

LASs (see Figure 55-1);<br />

29/09/09


823<br />

� Market-relevant information; and<br />

� A clear mechanism for reporting <strong>of</strong> data.<br />

Figure 55-1: Mass Balance Calculation for the LATS in England<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


56.0 Proposed <strong>Policy</strong> Changes<br />

This study (see Annexes 52.0 to 55.0) has reviewed evidence in respect <strong>of</strong>:<br />

824<br />

� Landfill taxes;<br />

� Landfill bans;<br />

� Incineration taxes;<br />

� Incineration bans;<br />

� Tradable allowances for landfilling;<br />

� Non-tradable allowances for landfilling;<br />

� Restrictions on landfilling through pre-treatment requirements.<br />

There are a number <strong>of</strong> studies which make comments about ‘what works’ and ‘what<br />

doesn’t’. There are differences in the views presented therein, but generally, the view<br />

is taken that the above instruments work in combination with others to steer waste<br />

into different management routes. There are differences in perspective depending<br />

upon whether the analysis is <strong>of</strong> household or municipal waste, or whether the<br />

emphasis is on landfill diversion alone or other management routes.<br />

Many commentators appear to lose sight <strong>of</strong> some basic principles <strong>of</strong> public policy. For<br />

example, bans on landfill may appear attractive, but they are economically inefficient.<br />

They are likely to impose high social costs unless they are targeted so as to eliminate<br />

relatively significant environmental problems at an acceptable cost.<br />

Although many argue in favour <strong>of</strong> landfill bans to promote movement <strong>of</strong> waste up the<br />

hierarchy, it is interesting to note that two countries which have applied widespread<br />

bans – Denmark and Netherlands – have done so with the objective <strong>of</strong> seeking to<br />

ensure incineration capacity is well utilised. In other words, the principle aim has<br />

been to shift material from landfill to incineration. In several other cases, landfill bans<br />

have been applied alongside high taxes for landfilling <strong>of</strong> untreated waste. Again, in<br />

these cases, to the extent that prices for landfill and alternatives are made ‘more or<br />

less equal’ by the tax, it can be appreciated why, when recycling and waste prevention<br />

find their motivation in the avoided costs <strong>of</strong> residual waste management / disposal,<br />

the introduction <strong>of</strong> bans on top <strong>of</strong> taxes has little effect on recycling and waste<br />

prevention. In many cases, therefore, the principle effect <strong>of</strong> bans and restrictions on<br />

landfilling appears to have been to give the market additional certainty regarding the<br />

financial case for developing alternative treatments to landfill.<br />

Regarding landfill taxes and incineration taxes, few countries have deployed these<br />

with a view to internalising externalities. Rather, these taxes have been used to<br />

achieve broader objectives <strong>of</strong> waste management policy, in particular, improving the<br />

financial viability <strong>of</strong> recycling and waste prevention, and providing incentives to<br />

engage in such activity.<br />

It is interesting to note that both Sweden and Denmark, which make considerable use<br />

<strong>of</strong> incineration, have high incineration taxes in place. This latter point highlights the<br />

29/09/09


need to consider not just ‘policy’ in the round, but also, the regulatory context and<br />

ownership structures in understanding how policy has developed.<br />

56.1 What Does Ireland Need?<br />

The current situation as outlined in Annex 51.0 highlights:<br />

825<br />

� That in 2007, the quantity <strong>of</strong> BMW landfilled was 518,535 in excess <strong>of</strong> what<br />

would be allowed in 2010;<br />

� That commercial waste is growing far more rapidly than household waste,<br />

though this degree to which this reflects reporting anomalies needs to be<br />

clarified;<br />

� That the capture <strong>of</strong> the largest biodegradable fraction in the municipal stream<br />

– the organics – was very low (9%);<br />

� That significant scope exists for increasing captures <strong>of</strong> paper and card;<br />

� That relevant ‘targets’ set at the national level do not cascade down to those<br />

who are actually delivering change on the ground; and<br />

� That regional plans are not equipped with the relevant information, and nor<br />

are they under any form <strong>of</strong> sanction, which would give anyone confidence that<br />

meeting <strong>of</strong> the NBS targets is assured through the Regional <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Plans. Indeed, it will be interesting to see whether any Region in<br />

Ireland meets ‘its share’ <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive target (accepting that no one<br />

actually has formally required them so to do).<br />

It would be preferable, in this context, if policy changes could achieve the following;<br />

� Give the market clear incentives to develop alternatives to waste being sent<br />

untreated to landfill;<br />

� Do so consistent with environmental objectives;<br />

� Give clarity concerning the role played by treatments such as MBT to the<br />

meeting <strong>of</strong> Landfill Directive targets;<br />

� Deliver some certainty <strong>of</strong> meeting future Landfill Directive targets without<br />

compromising future improvements in waste management;<br />

� Do so in such a way that the market for dealing with biodegradable waste<br />

suffers no undue disruption because <strong>of</strong> insufficient capacity.<br />

However, the time remaining before the first target must be met is incredibly short,<br />

and the luxury <strong>of</strong> developing policy and waiting for incentives to take effect is simply<br />

not available. In what follows, we consider short-term actions and policies intended to<br />

take effect over the longer term, but which need to be announced / enacted urgently<br />

if targets are to be met.<br />

56.1.1 Short-term Actions<br />

Unless recycling rates have changed very significantly since 2007, and unless the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> municipal waste has dipped sharply since 2007, then the gap between<br />

what is required, and what currently exists, seems unlikely to be met in the time<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


available. There are strong reasons to believe, however, that the economic downturn<br />

will have affected the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste generated, probably in both 2008 and 2009.<br />

ESRI forecasts a decline in GDP <strong>of</strong> 10% at market prices for 2009 and a further<br />

decline <strong>of</strong> 1.9% in 2010. 1032 It would be expected that this effect, with an impact on<br />

wages, would lead to a reduction in the overall quantity <strong>of</strong> municipal waste, though<br />

the balance across the household and non-household sectors might be difficult to<br />

estimate. We would assume that the response on the household waste side would be<br />

less dramatic than on the commercial side, partly reflecting a reversing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

apparent effects in the past in terms <strong>of</strong> growth.<br />

We have estimated that household waste and commercial waste fell by 1% and 3%,<br />

respectively, in 2008, 1033 and that growth rates will be -3% and -7% for household<br />

and commercial waste in 2009, and -1% and -2% for household and commercial<br />

waste in 2010. This would lead to a net fall <strong>of</strong> 8% in municipal waste by 2010 relative<br />

to 2007 figures. 1034<br />

The performance in respect <strong>of</strong> recycling <strong>of</strong> paper and card, and <strong>of</strong> organics, will be<br />

crucial if Ireland is to meet the 2010 Landfill Directive targets. The recycling <strong>of</strong> paper<br />

and card will have been stimulated by rising prices for secondary fibre in the first half<br />

<strong>of</strong> 2008 but it will have suffered in the second half <strong>of</strong> 2008. Prices are recovering<br />

again, so that it might be expected that by the end <strong>of</strong> 2009, capture rates (as a<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> total paper and card) might not be so different from 2007 levels<br />

(having increased in previous years). We have projected that the capture rate reaches<br />

55% in 2010, a slight increase from 2007 levels, but the same level as the EPA<br />

reports for 2006, and on track with the target set in the National Biodegradable<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Strategy.<br />

The situation regarding the organic waste stream then becomes crucial. Captures<br />

were shy <strong>of</strong> 9% in 2007, but the National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy sets a target<br />

<strong>of</strong> 25% by 2010. A 25% capture rate would imply organic waste treatment <strong>of</strong> around<br />

210,000 tonnes in 2010, up from 78,617 tonnes in 2007. This seems possible,<br />

given the ongoing roll-out <strong>of</strong> collections for organic waste (‘the brown bin’) and given<br />

also the potential biowaste treatment capacity in the country at the time <strong>of</strong> writing,<br />

although anecdotal evidence suggests this might be happening more slowly than had<br />

hitherto been the case. There is no room for complacency, and the key hurdle might<br />

appear to be the licensing and permitting <strong>of</strong> biowaste treatment capacity. Any delays<br />

could have significant implications for the overall approach, although as mentioned<br />

above, some are viewing spare capacity at rendering plants as a possible solution,<br />

possibly for an interim period.<br />

1032 ESRI (2009).<br />

1033 Although the economy was already in decline, CSO reports that net migration was still positive, with<br />

population increasing by some 80,000 over the year.<br />

1034 Recent UK figures, where the effect on GDP has been less dramatic than in Ireland, seem to<br />

suggest that some local authorities will report drops in municipal waste – which is defined more<br />

narrowly in the UK than in Ireland, and relates mostly to household waste – <strong>of</strong> as much as 10% from<br />

2008 to 2009. Our estimates may well be conservative (i.e. the extent <strong>of</strong> the decline may be much<br />

greater than we are predicting).<br />

826<br />

29/09/09


In the above scenario, with captures <strong>of</strong> textiles and wood kept constant, there would<br />

still be 227,592 tonnes more biodegradable waste in residual waste than could be<br />

landfilled (see Figure 56-1). This would be equivalent, in this year, to the BMW<br />

contained within a total <strong>of</strong> 323,564 tonnes <strong>of</strong> residual waste.<br />

Figure 56-1: Estimated Performance Against 2010 Landfill Directive Target (25%<br />

Capture <strong>of</strong> Organics, 55% Capture <strong>of</strong> Paper and Card, No Increase in Captures <strong>of</strong><br />

Textiles and Wood from 2007 Levels)<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Quantities (tonnes)<br />

827<br />

3,500,000<br />

3,000,000<br />

2,500,000<br />

2,000,000<br />

1,500,000<br />

1,000,000<br />

500,000<br />

0<br />

Distance to target =<br />

227,592 tonnes BMW<br />

2007 2008 2009 2010<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Year<br />

MSW<br />

BMW<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> Paper and Card<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> Textiles<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> Wood<br />

Collection <strong>of</strong> Biowaste for Composting /<br />

Digestion<br />

BMW in Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

If this scenario is deemed a credible starting point, then in order to meet targets, one<br />

or more <strong>of</strong> the following would need to happen:<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> quantities would need to be lower than projected here. Note that<br />

because it has not been made clear exactly how attempts to reduce the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste in the waste stream will be accounted for in<br />

Ireland, it is not clear how prevention activity will affect performance against<br />

the BMW targets. If the EPA’s intention is to assume that all households with a<br />

particular type <strong>of</strong> system generate waste <strong>of</strong> the same composition, then it may<br />

be just as beneficial to reduce the quantity <strong>of</strong> rubble as it will be to reduce the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> food waste; 1035<br />

� Paper and card recycling rates would need to be in excess <strong>of</strong> 55%. Our<br />

experience in the UK is that the addition <strong>of</strong> further materials to recycling<br />

1035 This is a problem – in terms <strong>of</strong> the perverse consequences <strong>of</strong> mass balance calculations – that<br />

has been widely discussed in the UK in the context <strong>of</strong> the LASs (see Annex 55.0).


828<br />

29/09/09<br />

collections has tended to improve the capture <strong>of</strong> those which were already<br />

being targeted. In particular, yields <strong>of</strong> dry recyclables have increased when<br />

biowaste collections have been introduced. This suggests there may be an<br />

effect on recycling rates for paper and card anyway, purely as a result <strong>of</strong> the<br />

roll-out <strong>of</strong> ‘brown bins’. There is likely to be some room for further<br />

improvement in services, but also, in the nature <strong>of</strong> incentives used to<br />

encourage waste producers to make use <strong>of</strong> recycling services already<br />

available;<br />

� The capture <strong>of</strong> organics would need to be in excess <strong>of</strong> 25% <strong>of</strong> total. This does<br />

not seem impossible from the perspective <strong>of</strong> collection, but a key hurdle would<br />

be the availability <strong>of</strong> suitable treatment capacity. This would, after all, need to<br />

be ‘on-stream’ for the whole <strong>of</strong> 2010 (i.e. up and running in five months time).<br />

This is clearly a challenge;<br />

� The capture <strong>of</strong> textiles would need to be increased, especially from the<br />

household stream. The textiles fraction as measured in the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Characterisation report, is unusually high for household waste (compared with<br />

other countries). 1036 However, around half <strong>of</strong> this is, on closer inspection,<br />

nappies. The recycling <strong>of</strong> textiles is, according to many studies, highly<br />

beneficial from the perspective <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gas emissions. 1037 It is notable<br />

that many collection permits do not specify a requirement to collect textiles<br />

separately. Figure 51-3 showed uncaptured textiles as the second largest<br />

single uncaptured fraction, after the organic fraction, in the household waste<br />

stream, but around half <strong>of</strong> this is nappies (so more amenable to waste<br />

prevention and re-use than recycling per se). 1038 The target capture in the<br />

National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy is 15% for 2010, but there is little by<br />

way <strong>of</strong> clear signs that this target will be met. 1039 The 15% target in the<br />

National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> strategy relates to all textiles, including<br />

nappies, so implies a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> the order 30% <strong>of</strong> non-nappy textiles.<br />

Prognos reports recycling rates <strong>of</strong> 41% for Austria, 46% for France, 49% for<br />

Belgium and 53% for Germany. 1040 It is not clear whether or not these ‘textile’<br />

1036 The EPA 2007 figures amount to around 50kg per inhabitant for Ireland in the municipal stream<br />

alone. Prognos reports that only Austria produces more textile waste than Ireland on a per capita basis,<br />

and that the average for EU countries is around 25kg per inhabitant. The figure reported for the<br />

household waste stream in <strong>Waste</strong> Characterisation reports is 12.2%. By way <strong>of</strong> comparison, the UK<br />

reports that textile wastes are around 3% <strong>of</strong> municipal waste (which, in the UK, is mainly household<br />

waste). Our experience in other countries suggests that figures <strong>of</strong> the order 4% are more typical,<br />

although the age <strong>of</strong> ‘the disposable clothing item’ is clearly encroaching as real prices fall.<br />

1037 See Annex 63.0.<br />

1038 There are proceses which can recycle nappies, but they essentially require the nappies to be<br />

collected separately in the first place.<br />

1039 It should be noted that the 15% target in the National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> strategy relates to all<br />

textiles, including nappies, so implies a recycling rate <strong>of</strong> the order 30% <strong>of</strong> non-nappy textiles.<br />

1040 Prognos (2008) European Atlas <strong>of</strong> Secondary Raw Materials: 2004 Status Quo and Potentials,<br />

January 2008.


829<br />

figures include nappies, as is the case in Ireland, but our experience suggests<br />

they would not. The general picture, however, is that there is very significant<br />

potential for progress to be made in this area in Ireland, and that through<br />

capturing around 50% <strong>of</strong> the non-nappy textiles, an additional 40,000 tonnes<br />

or so <strong>of</strong> landfilled waste could be avoided; 1041<br />

In the following scenario we have assumed that:<br />

� Growth rates are as previously projected;<br />

� The capture rate for paper and card increases to 60%;<br />

� Textiles recycling / re-use rates increase to 15% <strong>of</strong> total (around 30% <strong>of</strong> nonnappy<br />

textiles), in line with the National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy; and<br />

� Organic waste captures increase to 30% in 2010.<br />

Other material captures are increased slightly from the previous scenario (reflecting,<br />

as with paper and card, increased efforts to sort). The results from this scenario are<br />

shown in Figure 56-2. The Scenario would require capacity for treatment <strong>of</strong> source<br />

segregated organics to be <strong>of</strong> the order 250,000 tonnes, an increase <strong>of</strong> 170,000<br />

tonnes or so from 2007.<br />

A critical variable will be the change in gross quantities <strong>of</strong> MSW, and in particular, the<br />

effect that the recession has had upon this. Even so, they highlight the fact that even<br />

with these efforts, there would be 143,170 tonnes more BMW in residual waste than<br />

could be landfilled. This is equivalent to the BMW contained in 208,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

residual MSW.<br />

The treatment possibilities for this residual waste then become important. Here, there<br />

appear to be four possibilities:<br />

1. The residual waste is incinerated. There would appear to be only one<br />

possibility in this respect by 2010. This is the Carranstown plant at Meath,<br />

though it seems unlikely that this would be operating for the whole year, even<br />

if it was operating for part there<strong>of</strong> (and it might not be);<br />

2. The residual waste is used in the preparation <strong>of</strong> SRF for export. This has been<br />

happening for some years, with more that 30,000 tonnes exported to UK and<br />

Sweden in 2007;<br />

1041 It is far from clear to us why ‘textiles’ should be treated as 100% biodegradable for the purposes <strong>of</strong><br />

the Landfill Directive. There are many synthetic textiles available and the fact that Ireland’s<br />

performance in respect <strong>of</strong> capturing textiles is relatively poor simply increases the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the<br />

task ahead. Effectively, the approach overstates the quantity <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste in the waste<br />

stream, making it more difficult to meet a target in any given year. According to a recent life-cycle study<br />

on nappies, 16.8% <strong>of</strong> the weight <strong>of</strong> nappies disposed is not biodegradable (ERM (2008) An Updated<br />

Lifecycle Assessment Study for Disposable and Reusable Nappies, Report for WRAP and Defra,<br />

Science Report SC010018/SR2, October 2008). In the UK, it is generally assumed that 50% by weight<br />

<strong>of</strong> textiles are biodegradable, and whilst this may not be strictly accurate, it implies a pragmatic<br />

approach to the issue that not all textiles are biodegradable. This matter is taken up below.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


830<br />

3. The residual waste is used to prepare SRF for co-incineration at cement kilns.<br />

The capacity <strong>of</strong> the kilns is likely to be <strong>of</strong> the order 100,000 -150,000 tonnes<br />

SRF for the year. The issue is one <strong>of</strong> whether the facilities exist which can<br />

produce this quantity <strong>of</strong> SRF to the desired specification. Furthermore,<br />

depending upon the fuel preparation process, the SRF might have a<br />

biodegradable content <strong>of</strong> the order 60%, so that the SRF might contain 60-<br />

90,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> BMW;<br />

4. The residual waste is stabilised prior to being landfilled. Here, there are<br />

facilities which are primed for this purpose, but the question remains as to<br />

whether the incentive exists for this to occur. Some incentive may flow from<br />

the EPA’s Pre-treatment Guidelines.<br />

Figure 56-2: Estimated Performance Against 2010 Landfill Directive Target (30%<br />

Capture <strong>of</strong> Organics,60% Capture <strong>of</strong> Paper and Card, 15% Capture <strong>of</strong> Textiles)<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Quantities (tonnes)<br />

3,500,000<br />

3,000,000<br />

2,500,000<br />

2,000,000<br />

1,500,000<br />

1,000,000<br />

500,000<br />

29/09/09<br />

0<br />

Distance to target =<br />

143,170 tonnes BMW<br />

2007 2008 2009 2010<br />

Year<br />

MSW<br />

BMW<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> Paper and Card<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> Textiles<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> Wood<br />

Collection <strong>of</strong> Biowaste for Composting /<br />

Digestion<br />

BMW in Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

The sum total <strong>of</strong> these has the potential to deliver the required diversion from landfill.<br />

However, the prospects for meeting the 2010 target still appear to be slim. Indeed,<br />

even if all the above actions were deemed possible, it is not clear who really has the<br />

incentive to undertake them. Where the Landfill Directive is concerned, no one is<br />

faced with any target, let alone a sanction for not meeting it. This is a situation from<br />

which Ireland needs to learn (in terms <strong>of</strong> how targets set at the national level can be<br />

met).<br />

Much also depends on how the accounting against the targets is carried out. As noted<br />

above, there may be ways <strong>of</strong> reducing the target simply through specifying a<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> textiles that are biodegradable which more accurately reflects the<br />

reality, and is below the current 100% figure. Setting this at a highly plausible figure


<strong>of</strong> the order 65% would reduce the quantity <strong>of</strong> BMW in waste at the outset, and<br />

reduce the net quantity being landfilled, by around 70,000 tonnes. However, the<br />

1995 baseline would also be lower, so that the net improvement in the position re<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong> BMW would be <strong>of</strong> the order 50,000 tonnes. Given how close Ireland<br />

could be to meeting these targets, such a change – which merely improves the<br />

accuracy <strong>of</strong> the accounting – could be rather important in the final analysis.<br />

Possible means to achieve the target would need to include one or more <strong>of</strong> the<br />

following:<br />

831<br />

1. Rapid Rapid development development <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> home home composting composting for for municipal municipal biowastes;<br />

biowastes;<br />

Whilst this might be a useful and cost-effective measure for households, the<br />

increase in uptake <strong>of</strong> home composting might not be extraordinarily high,<br />

whilst for many households, home composting is not an option. A 5% increase<br />

in home composting would be a very significant result in the time available,<br />

but this would give an estimated benefit <strong>of</strong> only 13,230 tonnes. Nor is it clear<br />

how this would be accounted for – it is not clear that the reduction in waste<br />

would necessarily be registered as being <strong>of</strong> a wholly biodegradable nature.<br />

Finally, such campaigns do require planning and trained staff. They are<br />

unlikely to be successful in such a short space <strong>of</strong> time, so it seems likely that<br />

the best option would be to build upon existing schemes; 1042<br />

2. A A campaign campaign to to reduce reduce the the wastage wastage <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> food food (and (and other other waste waste prevention<br />

prevention<br />

campaigns);<br />

campaigns);<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action Programme (WRAP) ‘Love Food, Hate <strong>Waste</strong>’<br />

campaign has specifically targeted food waste, recognising the cost <strong>of</strong> wasted<br />

food to households and to the environment (embodied greenhouse gas<br />

benefits are estimated to be <strong>of</strong> the order 2.5 tonnes CO2 equ per tonne <strong>of</strong> food<br />

waste avoided). Even if 5% <strong>of</strong> all food waste could be prevented in the time<br />

available, the net benefit might be only <strong>of</strong> the order 30,000 tonnes. As with<br />

home composting, because it is not clear how this would be accounted for, it is<br />

not clear that the reduction in waste would necessarily be registered as being<br />

<strong>of</strong> a wholly biodegradable nature;<br />

3. Rapi Rapid Rapi Rapid<br />

d development development <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> facilities facilities to to deal deal with with BMW BMW in in residual residual waste.<br />

waste.<br />

So as not compromise efforts <strong>of</strong> those already advanced in developing plans<br />

for residual waste treatment, it might make sense to seek rapid procurement<br />

<strong>of</strong> MBT capacity for Ireland capable <strong>of</strong> carrying out basic pre-treatment <strong>of</strong><br />

waste to stabilise the material prior to landfilling. To the extent that this was<br />

deemed to meet threshold criteria, the aim <strong>of</strong> this would be to deliver the<br />

additional diversion necessary to meet the 2010 targets. However, it might be<br />

argued that several <strong>of</strong> the urban areas already have proposals in hand for<br />

incineration, and that the procured facilities might more usefully be targeted at<br />

rural areas. To the extent that this approach was favoured, development <strong>of</strong> the<br />

1042 CSO figures suggest Ireland has 1.47 million private households. We have assumed an average<br />

figure, taken from studies by WRAP, <strong>of</strong> 180kg per hhld, giving a total <strong>of</strong> 265,000 tonnes if all<br />

households were home composting (which, logically, they could not be).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


832<br />

29/09/09<br />

procurement strategy, and work to identify appropriate sites, would need to<br />

begin straightaway, and would probably still be too late to deliver what is<br />

necessary. However, it might be realistic to expect such a development to bear<br />

fruit only in a timescale <strong>of</strong> two years or so if this was prioritised by all relevant<br />

parties (notably in respect <strong>of</strong> permitting, planning and funding). Furthermore,<br />

these facilities would need to have some longer-term guarantee <strong>of</strong> waste into<br />

their plant, and so without commitments <strong>of</strong> waste for the medium- to longterm,<br />

they would be unlikely to be supported by debt finance, especially in the<br />

current economic climate;<br />

4. Identifying Identifying Identifying export export export markets markets markets for for residual residual residual BMW BMW BMW destined destined destined for for recovery recovery recovery facilities. facilities.<br />

facilities.<br />

Some SRF is already sent abroad for combustion in Sweden. The<br />

development <strong>of</strong> incineration capacity abroad is tending towards over-capacity<br />

in a number <strong>of</strong> situations. 1043 Given the high avoided cost <strong>of</strong> landfilling (higher<br />

with an increase to the waste levy as proposed – see Section 56.2.1) the<br />

potential to make use <strong>of</strong> surplus capacity abroad may be available. Clearly,<br />

exports would have to be destined to recovery facilities, so not all incinerators<br />

ought to be capable <strong>of</strong> receiving exports. Care would need to be taken to<br />

ensure appropriate safeguards were in place regarding exports.<br />

5. So So as as to to to buy buy some some some additional additional time time for for Ireland, Ireland, Ireland Ireland Ireland could could could consider consider baling baling <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

waste waste prior prior to to subsequent subsequent subsequent use.<br />

use.<br />

Baling tends to be applied to materials which are subjected to biodrying, with a<br />

view to later using the material as solid recovered fuel. However, this is a less<br />

than ideal solution, whilst the approach lends itself to temporary storage. It is<br />

not clear how temporary storage would need to be.<br />

There are a worryingly large number <strong>of</strong> unresolved matters in seeking to understand<br />

how efforts to meet the targets would be accounted for, let alone how they could be<br />

achieved. The task is a large one, and the starting point is not a particularly strong<br />

one.<br />

The scenario set out at Figure 56-1 is not entirely implausible, but the scenario is<br />

likely to see Ireland fail to deliver its 2010 targets unless growth is lower than we<br />

have indicated. The scenario depicted in Figure 56-2 would require a considerable<br />

mobilisation in a short period <strong>of</strong> time, and whilst this, along with changing the<br />

accounting method for textiles, could deliver on the targets, it is the time available,<br />

not the level <strong>of</strong> the achievement, which is the principle barrier.<br />

Furthermore, these changes would be having to be made concurrently with a range <strong>of</strong><br />

changes in policy and institutions which appear, in our view, necessary to improve the<br />

functioning <strong>of</strong> the waste management market and industry in Ireland. Evidently, at<br />

some point one has to ask whether the achievement <strong>of</strong> a target which, because<br />

changes might be being forced upon actors in an untimely manner, is expensive to<br />

achieve is worth the significant effort that would be required, recognising also that the<br />

2013 target is now looming rather large.<br />

1043 See, for example, the recent report by NABU (2009) Müllverbrennung in Deutschland wächst<br />

unkontrolliert – Recycling ist gefährdet, Müllimport wird attraktiver, Berlin, March 2009.


56.2 Proposed Policies to Deal with Residual <strong>Waste</strong> in the<br />

Context <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive<br />

In principle, three options appear to be available regarding the Landfill Directive:<br />

1) Re-couch the national targets as regional, or local authority ones, and implement<br />

a mechanism to ensure these are met. This might lead Ireland to a situation akin<br />

to the UK’s landfill allowances schemes, where <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Authorities are<br />

effectively allocated quotas <strong>of</strong> allowances limiting the quantity <strong>of</strong> biodegradable<br />

municipal waste they could landfill. One major difference between the UK and<br />

Ireland, however, is that local authorities have control over what happens with the<br />

totality <strong>of</strong> what is defined as municipal waste in the UK. The same is not true for<br />

Ireland, and nor would it be true if Irish local authorities were made directly<br />

responsible for the collection and management <strong>of</strong> household waste, as proposed<br />

in Section 3.6. The large (and, hitherto, rapidly growing) quantity <strong>of</strong> commercial<br />

waste would still be open to the marketplace to determine the management <strong>of</strong>.<br />

Hence, this mechanism does not seem to recommend itself, at least not for ‘all<br />

municipal waste’, since no addressee is appropriate for the target being proposed;<br />

2) A second option would be to choose an addressee for Landfill Directive targets<br />

that does have control over how waste is managed. By the time waste arrives at<br />

landfill, decisions have already been made, so this could not be the landfill<br />

operator itself, unless the main implementing mechanism was a requirement to<br />

pre-treat (see below). The only real alternative appears to be the collectors.<br />

Collectors could, in principle, be given landfill allowances relating to the proportion<br />

<strong>of</strong> (biodegradable) municipal waste they handle (another option would be to<br />

auction the allowances), this proportion declining each year. They would be<br />

allowed to trade these with other collectors so that those who had surplus<br />

allowances (who had recycled more, or ensured more waste was treated) could<br />

sell to those who were in deficit. One issue with this is that rather like the regions<br />

/ local authorities in Ireland, collectors are not always in a position to influence<br />

investments in treatment. The level <strong>of</strong> vertical integration across collection and<br />

treatment / disposal varies across collection companies. The mechanism might<br />

also compromise any efforts to develop indigenous infrastructure, with exports a<br />

likely means used to meet targets (rather more so than already happens). Finally,<br />

the required accounting mechanism would be difficult to design and implement in<br />

a fair manner, and there would be significant issues <strong>of</strong> moral hazard to be<br />

overcome; and<br />

3) A third option is to re-cast policy such that, whatever other instruments are in<br />

place, the market is incentivised and regulated to deliver on the targets. Here, a<br />

wide range <strong>of</strong> options are available, and they could, in principle, be considered.<br />

However, as highlighted above, there are some key policies already in<br />

development regarding residual waste and the Landfill Directive. In essence, we<br />

believe that with some adaptation, these will take Ireland a long way to meeting<br />

its Landfill Directive targets in 2013. The 2010 issues are clearly more pressing,<br />

as discussed above.<br />

833<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


56.2.1 A <strong>Waste</strong> Levy<br />

The existing landfill levy is too low. Everyone appears to agree with this, but this does<br />

not mean landfill taxes should be increased ad infinitum. Principles <strong>of</strong> public policy<br />

suggest that some justification for a level <strong>of</strong> taxation should be provided, and the<br />

most solid justification (at least in the sense <strong>of</strong> the principle) is the internalisation <strong>of</strong><br />

externalities associated with the activity in question.<br />

The measurement <strong>of</strong> these, however, proves to be somewhat more difficult. We have<br />

provided a review <strong>of</strong> literature on the external costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> residual waste<br />

treatments in Annex 61.0. This highlights the fact that the literature is far from<br />

equivocal, even where the preference for landfill vis a vis incineration is concerned,<br />

especially where attempts are made to consider all social costs.<br />

Several actors, organisations and bodies highlight the desirability <strong>of</strong> using life-cycle<br />

assessment to determine preferences for the environmental performance <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

facilities. However, life-cycle approaches, whilst usefully setting out estimates <strong>of</strong><br />

possible impact in different assessment categories, do not use a common metric that<br />

enable easy alignment with environmental damages, as monetised through economic<br />

techniques. Indeed, in our view, life-cycle assessment approaches are more shaky in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> the insight they bring to the complex systems we are dealing with. By way <strong>of</strong><br />

illustration, in Annex 62.0, we have carried out some comparative analysis using the<br />

tool WRATE, developed by the Environment Agency in England and Wales, to show<br />

how the choice <strong>of</strong> facilities and impact assessment methods can shift analysis in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> one or other facility. This seemed relevant given that some recent modelling<br />

using this tool was undertaken in a recent appraisal <strong>of</strong> the performance <strong>of</strong> MBT for<br />

the EPA. 1044<br />

Over many years, Eunomia has developed an in-house model <strong>of</strong> residual waste<br />

treatments which allows for the modelling <strong>of</strong> both life-cycle impacts <strong>of</strong> facilities and<br />

their external costs and benefits. This model has been used in analyses for many<br />

local authorities in the UK, for the UK’s Committee on Climate Change and WRAP, and<br />

for other bodies such as the Greater London Authority. In this study, we have<br />

modelled the external costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> different residual waste treatment<br />

options with a view to understanding how a waste levy might be structured, and to<br />

understand the relationship it bears to the levy already proposed as part <strong>of</strong> the<br />

aforementioned RIA. 1045 Details <strong>of</strong> the modelling are given in Annex 63.0.<br />

We have modelled the following treatments<br />

1) Landfill, Landfill, untreated untreated residual municipal waste ( (RMSW (<br />

RMSW RMSW) RMSW (50% (50% lifetime lifetime capture)<br />

capture)<br />

This is a landfill where the gas capture rate is set at 50% over the facility’s<br />

lifetime;<br />

1044 Fehily Timoney & Company / Veolia Environmental Services / Ramboll (2008) Critical Analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

the Potential for Mechanical Biological Treatment for Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Volume 2, Research<br />

Report, Report for the Environmental Protection Agency, September 2008.<br />

1045 AP EnvEcon (forthcoming) Regulatory Impact Analysis on Proposed Legislation to Increase Levies<br />

on Shopping Bags and Certain <strong>Waste</strong> Facilities, Final Report.<br />

834<br />

29/09/09


2) Incineration, Incineration, Incineration, RMSW RMSW RMSW – WI WI WI Directive Directive Directive compliant compliant<br />

compliant<br />

This is an incinerator which ‘just complies’ with the emissions limit values under<br />

the <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration Directive<br />

3) Incineration, Incineration, Incineration, RMSW RMSW RMSW – State State-<strong>of</strong> State <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>-the <strong>of</strong> the the-art the art art Flue Flue Flue Gas Gas Gas Cleaning Cleaning<br />

Cleaning<br />

This is an incinerator whose performance far exceeds that required the emissions<br />

limit values under the <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration Directive;<br />

4) MBT, MBT, Stabilisation Stabilisation <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, <strong>Waste</strong>, All All Residue Residue to to Landfill Landfill (50% (50% lifetime lifetime capture)<br />

capture)<br />

This is a basic stabilisation facility where the principle objective is to ensure the<br />

residue is more stable before it is landfilled, thereby reducing methane emissions.<br />

The landfill is assumed to be the same as at 1) above. The level <strong>of</strong> stability<br />

achieved is in line with the standard outlined in the Second Draft Biowaste<br />

Directive, suggested as being sufficient to render waste no longer biodegradable<br />

for the purposes <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive;<br />

5) MBT, Biodrying, Biodrying, RDF to Incineration, Residue to Landfill (50% (50% lifetime lifetime capture)<br />

capture)<br />

This is a biodrying facility where the principle objective is to use energy from<br />

biodegradation, as well as air passing through the mass <strong>of</strong> material, to dry the<br />

material. The material is then subject to some sorting to derive a solid recovered<br />

fuel which is sent for incineration. The unrecycled residue is stabilised before it is<br />

landfilled, thereby reducing methane emissions. The landfill is assumed to be the<br />

same as at 1) above;<br />

6) MBT, MBT, Stabilisation Stabilisation <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, <strong>Waste</strong>, All All Residue Residue to to Landfill Landfill (dedicated (dedicated cells)<br />

cells)<br />

This is as for 4) but the landfill is assumed to be a dedicated cell, operated with<br />

the intention <strong>of</strong> maximising oxidation <strong>of</strong> fugitive methane (0% gas capture);<br />

7) MBT, Biodrying, Biodrying, RDF RDF to Incineration, Residue to to Landfill (dedicated (dedicated (dedicated cells)<br />

cells)<br />

This is as for 5) but the landfill is assumed to be a dedicated cell, operated with<br />

the intention <strong>of</strong> maximising oxidation <strong>of</strong> fugitive methane (0% gas capture).<br />

The results are shown in Table 56-1. Key features are, amongst others, that:<br />

835<br />

1. The externality assessment for landfill and ‘just-compliant’ incineration is in<br />

line with the proposed levy rates as set out in the RIA. This is especially true for<br />

the mid-point between the high and low damage costs. This is coincidence.<br />

The RIA set about establishing the level <strong>of</strong> the levy through seeking to ‘more or<br />

less equalize’ the costs <strong>of</strong> MBT, incineration and landfill. In doing this, it made<br />

assumptions regarding the cost <strong>of</strong> those facilities. Our assessment relates only<br />

to externalities, and makes no assumption at all about the costs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

facilities;<br />

2. If the incinerator is operated with state-<strong>of</strong>-the-art abatement equipment,<br />

however, externalities are considerably reduced;<br />

3. This is also apparent where the MBT Biodrying plant, which is deemed to send<br />

RDF for incineration, switches the destination for the RDF from a ‘just<br />

compliant’ incinerator to a state-<strong>of</strong>-the-art incinerator;<br />

4. For the MBT treatments, some material is sent to landfill. The performance <strong>of</strong><br />

the landfill significantly affects the results:<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


836<br />

29/09/09<br />

a. Where the residues are landfilled at a ‘standard landfill’, with assumed<br />

50% gas capture, then the Biodrying facilities perform better than<br />

stabilisation facilities.;<br />

b. Where the residues are landfilled at dedicated cells, with assumed 0%<br />

gas capture, but 90% oxidation, then the Biodrying facilities perform<br />

worse than Stabilisation facilities. The switch in ordering relates to the<br />

landfill’s performance and to the mass <strong>of</strong> material destined for the<br />

landfill. The significance <strong>of</strong> this is explored below;<br />

c. Where the stabilisation facility sends material to a dedicated cell, which<br />

is designed to maximise passive oxidation <strong>of</strong> residual methane, the<br />

externalities using high unit damage costs are very close to the<br />

maximum levy rate proposed for landfilling stabilised biowaste in the<br />

RIA <strong>of</strong> the proposed levy. 1046<br />

This analysis suggests that the levy rates are broadly justifiable, and would appear to<br />

have the potential to improve the management <strong>of</strong> waste in a positive direction, in line<br />

with what is efficient from the economic perspective. However, some adjustment to<br />

the currently proposed levy would appear to be desirable to improve the efficiency <strong>of</strong><br />

its design.<br />

The analysis above highlights the fact that the externalities from incineration are<br />

significantly affected by the performance in terms <strong>of</strong> the air emissions other than<br />

greenhouse gases. The difference is €6 per tonne where low unit damage costs are<br />

used in the analysis, or €21 per tonne where high unit damage costs are used. The<br />

magnitude <strong>of</strong> this difference is sufficient to warrant consideration as to how the levy<br />

could be designed to incentivise a reduction in these externalities.<br />

The design <strong>of</strong> the Norwegian incinerator tax provides a useful pointer (see 52.2.4).<br />

There, the tax focuses on emissions <strong>of</strong> each pollutant. These have to be monitored<br />

anyway by the facility. Hence, it ought to be possible to tax the source <strong>of</strong> the<br />

externality, the first best solution in this case. We propose, therefore, that the<br />

incineration levy might be adapted in its structure. A more efficient levy would be:<br />

� a per tonne levy for waste treatment, reflecting the climate change damages<br />

from carbon dioxide releases (there is rather limited potential to abate these<br />

emissions); and<br />

� a levy based upon emissions <strong>of</strong> key pollutants.<br />

Structured in this way, the levy affords the operators to abate emissions to an<br />

efficient level.<br />

1046 This is, perhaps, where the EPA might usefully focus its determination <strong>of</strong> BAT for landfills receiving<br />

residues from MBT facilities which meet the pre-treatment stability threshold. The operation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

landfill appears to have a more important effect on the environmental performance <strong>of</strong> the overall<br />

treatment and disposal cycle than the additional retention <strong>of</strong> the waste to achieve a small additional<br />

reduction in the tendency to produce biogas once landfilled.


Table 56-1: Levies Proposed in RIA, and Estimated Externalities from Treatments<br />

Landfill, untreated<br />

RMSW<br />

(50% lifetime<br />

capture)<br />

Incineration, RMSW<br />

– WI Directive<br />

compliant<br />

Incineration, RMSW<br />

– State-<strong>of</strong>-the-art<br />

Flue Gas Cleaning<br />

MBT, Stabilisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, All<br />

Residue to Landfill<br />

(50% lifetime<br />

capture)<br />

MBT, Biodrying, RDF<br />

to Incineration,<br />

Residue to Landfill<br />

(50% lifetime<br />

capture)<br />

MBT, Stabilisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, All<br />

Residue to Landfill<br />

(dedicated cells)<br />

MBT, Biodrying, RDF<br />

to Incineration,<br />

Residue to Landfill<br />

(dedicated cells)<br />

MBT, Biodrying, RDF<br />

to State <strong>of</strong> the Art<br />

Incineration,<br />

Residue to Landfill<br />

(dedicated cells)<br />

Landfilling <strong>of</strong><br />

Stabilised Biowaste<br />

837<br />

Proposed Proposed Levy Levy<br />

Levy<br />

Levels, Levels, 2011<br />

2011<br />

(€/tonne) €/tonne)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Proposed Proposed Levy<br />

Levy<br />

Levels,<br />

Levels,<br />

Maximum Maximum Rate<br />

Rate<br />

(€/tonne) €/tonne)<br />

Calculated<br />

Calculated<br />

Externalities,<br />

Externalities,<br />

Externalities,<br />

High High End End<br />

End<br />

Damage Damage Damage Costs<br />

Costs<br />

(€/tonne) €/tonne) €/tonne)<br />

Calculated<br />

Calculated<br />

Externalities,<br />

Externalities,<br />

Low Low End End<br />

End<br />

Damage Damage Damage Costs<br />

Costs<br />

(€/tonne) €/tonne)<br />

75 85 86 65<br />

22 45 51 31<br />

0 20<br />

32 25<br />

38 31<br />

35 24<br />

19 16<br />

31 21<br />

25 19<br />

Source: AP EnvEcon (forthcoming) Regulatory Impact Analysis on Proposed<br />

Legislation to Increase Levies on Shopping Bags and Certain <strong>Waste</strong> Facilities, Final<br />

Report.<br />

As regards the MBT processes, the impacts are affected by the type <strong>of</strong> treatment and<br />

the fate <strong>of</strong> the materials. Some <strong>of</strong> the externalities are associated with the pretreatment<br />

step, others are associated with the management <strong>of</strong> residues. It may make<br />

sense to structure the levy as follows:<br />

• A per tonne levy on the process itself;


838<br />

29/09/09<br />

• A per tonne levy for landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste at conventional landfills; and<br />

• A lower levy rate for landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste at landfills designed so as to<br />

minimise the unoxidised methane escaping from the landfill (through use<br />

<strong>of</strong>, for example, passive oxidation layers). The specification <strong>of</strong> this type <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill cell would need to take place under the auspices <strong>of</strong> the EPA, but it<br />

would allow for additional environmental benefits to be gained from the<br />

overall treatment process. 1047<br />

As will become clear below, we expect that the latter landfill type would become more<br />

common over time.<br />

It is crucial that the levy for stabilised waste is linked to a standard for assessing the<br />

stability <strong>of</strong> waste. Like the EPA Consultation Guidance, we recommend using the<br />

standard set in the EU Working Document on Biological Treatment <strong>of</strong> Biowaste 2 nd<br />

Draft: 1048<br />

‘stabilisation’ means the reduction <strong>of</strong> the decomposition properties <strong>of</strong><br />

biowaste to such an extent that <strong>of</strong>fensive odours are minimised and that<br />

either the Respiration Activity after four days (AT4) is below 10 mg O2/g dm or<br />

the Dynamic Respiration Index is below 1,000 mg O2/kg VS/h<br />

This is for the simple reason that the measure needs to be agreed quickly (to give<br />

effect to the levy) and experience from the UK suggests that deliberation on this<br />

measurement can lead to unfamiliar measurement approaches which make it<br />

impossible for developers to know how their technology will fare under a given<br />

measurement method.<br />

Meetings with the EPA suggest that in the Final Version <strong>of</strong> the Guidance, the stability<br />

criterion might be changed over time, dropping from 10 mg O2 / g dm to 7mg O2 /g<br />

dm, the latter being the Austrian standard (see 52.2.4). We question the rationale for<br />

moving from one standard to the other for the following reasons:<br />

1. The difference in environmental performance is likely to be insignificant, yet<br />

the impact on costs might be significant. The benefit relative to the cost would<br />

appear to be unjustified.<br />

2. The effects on the capacity <strong>of</strong> a facility effectively change when the stability<br />

criterion changes (and this is equivalent to the effect on costs mentioned<br />

above). This is the lesson <strong>of</strong> the German experience, where some stabilisation<br />

facilities, which used to operate as double duty sites, had to shut down the<br />

composting side <strong>of</strong> the plant because the capacity <strong>of</strong> facilities was<br />

1047 When stabilised waste is landfilled, then to the extent that it is properly stabilised in line with an<br />

appropriate threshold value, the aim is not so much to capture gas for energy generation. Rather, the<br />

objective is to deal with the much reduced fluxes <strong>of</strong> methane in such a way that they are not emitted to<br />

the atmosphere as methane, and passive oxidation at the landfill surface <strong>of</strong>fers the potential to<br />

achieve this as long as the methane fluxes through the surface are sufficiently low (allowing oxidation<br />

through the surface).<br />

1048 EPA (2008) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> - Pre-treatment and Residuals <strong>Management</strong>: An EPA Technical<br />

Guidance Document, Consultation Draft, Johnstown Castle Estate: EPA.


839<br />

dramatically reduced by marginal tightening <strong>of</strong> the stability criterion<br />

(increasing the required residence time, and hence the capacity <strong>of</strong> the plant to<br />

treat waste);<br />

3. It is unclear what rationale could be <strong>of</strong>fered for a stability measure that is<br />

different in one year to that set in another; and<br />

4. To the extent that it is to be used as the basis for establishing when waste can<br />

be considered no longer biodegradable for the purposes <strong>of</strong> the Landfill<br />

Directive, this has already been considered at some length by the European<br />

Commission, and the 10 mg O2 / g dm was deemed adequate.<br />

The standard would essentially:<br />

� Allow for the application <strong>of</strong> a lower tax rate than for untreated waste in the<br />

short-term:<br />

� Set the basis for a ban on landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste which fails to meet this standard<br />

in the medium- to long-term; and<br />

� Importantly, it would make explicit the fact that meeting the standard rendered<br />

the waste no longer biodegradable for the purposes <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive.<br />

It is important to recognise that the above externality assessments do attribute<br />

external benefits to energy generated at different facilities. It is entirely consistent to<br />

apply a levy to address the external costs <strong>of</strong> pollution whilst also seeking to<br />

incentivise the generation <strong>of</strong> renewable energy (although the latter is not the first best<br />

solution since the more efficient policy would be to tax the pollution from nonrenewable<br />

sources).<br />

It is worth pointing out, however, that to the extent that other policies internalise<br />

benefits associated with energy generation, then the uninternalised externalities<br />

which a waste levy should consider will, other things being equal, increase for those<br />

facilities upon which policy bestows a benefit. In other words, the level <strong>of</strong> the levy<br />

should consider the effects <strong>of</strong> other policies to the extent that they internalise<br />

benefits associated with the treatment. As stated above, however, the way in which<br />

REFIT will support municipal waste treatment facilities is not clear, though an<br />

estimation <strong>of</strong> benefits received by landfill operators is easier to discern.<br />

The suggested levy structure is below. Note that the rates proposed are in nominal<br />

terms, so we have allowed for some price inflation over this period. Our proposal<br />

involves some changes in structure and design from the initial proposal. The changes<br />

are designed to reward environmental improvement where this is deemed feasible.<br />

Incinerator operators, in particular, will be able to choose the level <strong>of</strong> abatement they<br />

use to optimise their exposure to the levy. The landfilling <strong>of</strong> stabilised biowaste is also<br />

affected by the nature <strong>of</strong> the receiving landfill.<br />

It is important to state that the first announcement <strong>of</strong> the levy must make clear what<br />

the levy rates will be for the foreseeable future. In other words, the rates for the years<br />

2010 to 2015 must be announced in 2010 so as to give the market confidence. We<br />

would suggest that a commitment is made to increase the proposed rates in Table<br />

56-2 in the years after 2012 at the Retail Price Index to maintain their value in real<br />

terms.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 56-2: Suggested Levy Structure<br />

Landfill, untreated<br />

RMSW<br />

840<br />

29/09/09<br />

RIA RIA Proposed<br />

Levy Levy Levels,<br />

Levels,<br />

2011<br />

2011<br />

(€/tonne) €/tonne)<br />

RIA RIA Proposed<br />

Levy Levy Levels,<br />

Levels,<br />

Maximum Maximum Rate<br />

Rate<br />

(€/tonne) €/tonne)<br />

75 85<br />

Incineration 22 45<br />

MBT processes<br />

Landfilling <strong>of</strong><br />

Stabilised Biowaste,<br />

Standard Landfill<br />

Landfilling <strong>of</strong><br />

Stabilised Biowaste,<br />

Dedicated Cell<br />

0 20<br />

0 20<br />

Eunomia<br />

Eunomia<br />

Prop Proposed Prop sed levy,<br />

2010<br />

2010<br />

2011<br />

2011<br />

2012<br />

2012<br />

€40/t<br />

€60/t<br />

€85/t<br />

€10 /t<br />

€20 /t<br />

€24 /t<br />

plus non-GHG<br />

pollutant related<br />

taxes<br />

(per kg <strong>of</strong><br />

pollutant)<br />

NH3 € 9.15<br />

VOCs € 2.50<br />

PM2.5 € 52.00<br />

SOx € 17.30<br />

NOx € 13.60<br />

Cd € 26.00<br />

Cr € 21.00<br />

Hg € 7,400.00<br />

Ni € 2.60<br />

Pb € 740.00<br />

Dioxin 46,000,000<br />

As € 99.00<br />

€5/t<br />

€12/t<br />

€20/t<br />

€5 /t<br />

€15 /t<br />

€25 /t<br />

€0/t<br />

€0/t<br />

€5/t<br />

56.2.2 A Ban on Landfilling <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Exceeding a Threshold<br />

Biodegradability<br />

We have reviewed a wide range <strong>of</strong> landfill bans across Europe. These tend to relate<br />

to:<br />

1) Household waste<br />

2) Segregated fractions <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

3) Biodegradable waste


4) Combustible waste<br />

5) <strong>Waste</strong> exceeding a stability standard; and<br />

6) <strong>Waste</strong> exceeding a threshold calorific value.<br />

What is <strong>of</strong> particular interest is the rationale for these, and how they are actually<br />

implemented. Implementing a ban on landfilling is not entirely straightforward, and in<br />

several countries where they are in place, exceptions have to be applied to allow for<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong> materials for which there is insufficient treatment capacity. In some<br />

countries, a key objective has been to shift was from landfill and into incineration.<br />

Bans are blunt instruments. They are, by definition, economically inefficient. They will<br />

not always lead, unequivocally, to environmental benefits and they may impose<br />

significant costs. Hence, to the extent that bans are deployed, they need to be<br />

considered carefully in order to ensure that gains are commensurate with costs. It is<br />

also worth considering that the practicalities <strong>of</strong> implementing and enforcing a ban<br />

limits the degree to which such bans can be targeted in ways which might, on purely<br />

environmental grounds, appear desirable (for example, banning food waste from<br />

landfill is extremely difficult unless whole waste streams are banned from landfill, or<br />

unless the ‘ban’ implies a requirement to source separate, in which case, it in not,<br />

strictly speaking, a ban).<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the bans which seem more likely to deliver benefits are those which are not,<br />

strictly speaking, outright bans. The above assessment <strong>of</strong> externalities suggests that,<br />

to the extent that the externalities <strong>of</strong> landfill are associated with biodegradable<br />

wastes, then treating waste to reduce that biodegradability seems to render<br />

significant benefits. This implies not so much a ‘ban’ as a restriction on the<br />

characteristics <strong>of</strong> wastes which can be landfilled. Our review highlights Austrian and<br />

German experience in this regard. These countries use broader criteria to restrict<br />

wastes sent to landfill. For example, in Austria, wastes which exceed a specified<br />

calorific value cannot be landfilled. However, in our view, this type <strong>of</strong> criterion is far<br />

less justified as the basis for a landfill ban. The presumption, presumably, is either<br />

that waste with a higher calorific value is better utilised in energy from waste plants,<br />

or that the environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> landfilling waste are somehow correlated with<br />

their calorific value. Neither is true, and brief consideration <strong>of</strong> how plastics fare in<br />

landfills and incinerators in respect <strong>of</strong> climate change supports this point. 1049<br />

The restructured levy, discussed above, will give a signal to the market that all<br />

residual waste treatments are to be made more expensive, most notably, landfilling <strong>of</strong><br />

untreated waste. This will move waste up the hierarchy and will give the market<br />

greater certainty in respect <strong>of</strong> developments other than landfilling.<br />

1049 We have discussed this elsewhere (D. Hogg (2006) A Changing Climate for Energy from <strong>Waste</strong>?<br />

Report to Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth). Subsequently, Defra stated, in <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy for England 2007,<br />

‘Burning plastics has a general net, adverse greenhouse gas impact due to the release <strong>of</strong> fossil<br />

carbon. Recycling shows significant potential for carbon and energy savings through displacing virgin<br />

materials, although the scale <strong>of</strong> this varies widely with the processing route.’ The same conclusion was<br />

reached in previous work for the European Commission (see Smith, A., K. Brown, S. Ogilvie, K. Rushton<br />

and J. Bates (2001) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options and Climate Change, Final Report to the European<br />

Commission, DG Environment, July 2001).<br />

841<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


This will not, however, give any certainty regarding the meeting <strong>of</strong> Landfill Directive<br />

targets. If a treatment for residual waste has the same cost as landfill, inclusive <strong>of</strong><br />

levies, then the chances are that the treatment facility will not be built for the simple<br />

reason that the landfill option still exists, and the landfill operator might be better<br />

placed to drop prices in the short terms than the treatment facility. Additional<br />

certainty is required, and this ought to be achieved under the EPA’s proposed pretreatment<br />

approach.<br />

We have proposed that the levy is announced and increased over a period <strong>of</strong> three<br />

years. We would suggest that to give certainty to the meeting <strong>of</strong> Landfill Directive<br />

targets, a ban on the landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste which does not meet the 10 mg O2/g d.m.<br />

stability criterion is implemented in 2013. We also suggest that some thought is given<br />

to the potential need for exemptions from the restriction in situations where, come<br />

2013, insufficient treatment capacity is available (locally). The lesson <strong>of</strong> the Dutch<br />

experience, however, is that if exemptions are available, some may seek to avail<br />

themselves <strong>of</strong> them indefinitely. Consequently, if a waste holder has no option other<br />

than to landfill residual waste, such an exemption could be granted, but at a cost to<br />

the holder <strong>of</strong> the waste. This ‘exemption levy’ should maintain the stimulus to build<br />

alternative treatments to landfill.<br />

56.3 ‘Government <strong>Policy</strong>’ and the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive<br />

It should be noted that non-incineration technologies for dealing with residual waste<br />

are unlikely to be developed as long as the perceived view is that ‘government policy<br />

is that residual waste should be incinerated’.<br />

It is widely held that Government policy is to favour thermal treatment over other<br />

forms <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment. There is, it would appear, no clear and<br />

unequivocal reason to support thermal treatment over other forms <strong>of</strong> residual waste<br />

treatment, and in any case, to the extent that the levy proposed above simply seeks<br />

to internalise externalities, the levy itself effectively removes the rationale for any<br />

such explicit discrimination – the aim <strong>of</strong> the levy is to allow the market to determine<br />

which facility is most appropriate.<br />

In European law, the revised <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive proposes that incinerators<br />

which exceed a specific threshold <strong>of</strong> efficiency in energy generation should be defined<br />

as ‘recovery’. The conditions are as follows:<br />

842<br />

29/09/09<br />

This includes incineration facilities dedicated to the processing <strong>of</strong> municipal<br />

solid waste only where their energy efficiency is equal to or above:<br />

— 0,60 for installations in operation and permitted in accordance with<br />

applicable Community legislation before 1 January 2009,<br />

— 0,65 for installations permitted after 31 December 2008,<br />

using the following formula:<br />

Energy efficiency = (Ep - (Ef + Ei))/(0,97 × (Ew + Ef))<br />

In which:<br />

Ep means annual energy produced as heat or electricity. It is calculated with<br />

energy in the form <strong>of</strong> electricity being multiplied by 2,6 and heat produced for<br />

commercial use multiplied by 1,1 (GJ/year)<br />

Ef means annual energy input to the system from fuels contributing to the<br />

production <strong>of</strong> steam (GJ/year)


843<br />

Ew means annual energy contained in the treated waste calculated using the<br />

net calorific value <strong>of</strong> the waste (GJ/year)<br />

Ei means annual energy imported excluding Ew and Ef (GJ/year)<br />

0,97 is a factor accounting for energy losses due to bottom ash and radiation.<br />

This formula shall be applied in accordance with the reference document on<br />

Best Available Techniques for waste incineration.<br />

In order to meet this criterion, a new facility generating only electricity has to exceed<br />

24.25% gross efficiency even if no energy is used in the process itself (in other words,<br />

even if Ei and Ef are set equal to zero in the above formula). Including the energy use,<br />

a report by CEWEP suggests that at existing plants generating mainly electricity, 6 <strong>of</strong><br />

25 facilities reviewed would meet the threshold for new facilities. 1050<br />

Although facilities which met this threshold efficiency level would be classified as<br />

‘recovery’ under the revised Directive, this does not necessarily confer upon such<br />

plants a preferred position in the hierarchy over all other residual waste treatments.<br />

Article 4 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive states:<br />

When applying the waste hierarchy referred to in paragraph 1, Member States<br />

shall take measures to encourage the options that deliver the best overall<br />

environmental outcome. This may require specific waste streams departing from<br />

the hierarchy where this is justified by life-cycle thinking on the overall impacts <strong>of</strong><br />

the generation and management <strong>of</strong> such waste.<br />

Given this, it might have been expected that the Commission itself would have sought<br />

to demonstrate a clear distinction between incinerator which would, and would not,<br />

meet the recovery criteria. To the best <strong>of</strong> our knowledge, it did not. Given that a trade<strong>of</strong>f<br />

may exist, in some instances, between an incinerator’s energy use, and the quality<br />

<strong>of</strong> flue gas cleaning, such an analysis would have been entirely appropriate.<br />

The above externality assessment, as well as the analysis in Annexes 61.0 and 62.0,<br />

suggests that for municipal waste, there is no obvious reason why incineration which<br />

qualifies as recovery should be preferred to some other forms <strong>of</strong> residual waste<br />

treatment. Even with respect to landfilling <strong>of</strong> untreated waste, surprisingly, the<br />

evidence is equivocal, including some <strong>of</strong> the work carried out under auspices <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European Commission itself. The <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive is also not well adapted<br />

to answering questions as to whether, and if so, under what conditions, different<br />

configurations <strong>of</strong> MBT should be regarded as recovery or disposal.<br />

In the light <strong>of</strong> the above, Government may wish to consider issuing a statement to the<br />

effect that as regards residual waste, the levy is intended to internalise environmental<br />

costs. With these estimated externalities internalised through the levy, other factors<br />

would be used to determine the pattern <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment used, including<br />

other policy instruments and their effects. Indeed, it is not clear what is to be gained<br />

by Government stating a preference for one or other approach to dealing with residual<br />

1050 D.O. Reimann (2006) CEWEP Energy Report, Report for CEWEP, Update July 2006.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


waste if the levy comes into force, with the key issue then being to ensure that policy<br />

seeks to minimise the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste which is managed as ‘residual waste’. 1051<br />

1051 Note that given the requests for evidence we have received, we have, for the sake <strong>of</strong><br />

completeness, carried out an assessment <strong>of</strong> external benefits from recycling. These would indicate a<br />

case for subsidy rather than a levy because <strong>of</strong> the external benefits generated. This will be made<br />

available at a later date, and to support the work on policy measures operating at higher levels in the<br />

hierarchy.<br />

844<br />

29/09/09


OTHER POLICIES<br />

845<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


57.0 Green Public Procurement<br />

57.1 Introduction<br />

The European Commission uses the following definition for green public procurement:<br />

846<br />

29/09/09<br />

“Green public procurement means that public purchasers take account <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental factors when buying products, services or works”.<br />

European and national legislation strictly governs public procurement in order to<br />

ensure the following three main objectives are achieved:<br />

� best value for money;<br />

� equal treatment <strong>of</strong> bidders; and<br />

� transparency <strong>of</strong> contract specifications and criteria.<br />

Green public procurement accounts for environmental issues through the contract by<br />

ensuring value for money.<br />

The environmental impact <strong>of</strong> a good or service can be displayed through eco-labelling<br />

or environmental management system certification. Eco-labelling is very <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

informed through Life Cycle Analysis (LCA) calculations. LCA proves that the products<br />

chosen, and eco-labelled, have a reduced environmental impact throughout their life<br />

cycle. This also demonstrates that green procurement is a cost-effective process<br />

when life-time, not just purchase costs, are taken account <strong>of</strong>. Eco-labelling, is usually<br />

voluntary and requires the product to be certified by a third party, having reached a<br />

certain environmental quality standard. The best-known <strong>of</strong> the eco-labels is the<br />

European label, which is a flower, whilst other successful systems are operating in<br />

Scandinavia, whose logo is the Nordic Swan, and Germany which use a Blue Angel<br />

logo. 1052 Also, environmental management systems such as EMAS and ISO140001<br />

are used as recognisable certification systems. In addition, several Member States<br />

have compiled databases <strong>of</strong> accredited green products and links to possible<br />

suppliers. 1053<br />

Green public procurement (GPP) is defined somewhat differently to sustainable<br />

procurement, which aims to account for social, ethical and environmental issues<br />

throughout the procurement process, although frequently the terms are used<br />

interchangeably.<br />

1052 European Commission (2004) Buying Green! – A Handbook on Environmental Public Procurement,<br />

Available: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/buying_green_handbook_en.pdf<br />

1053 ICLEI Local Governments for Sustainability (2007) The Procura+ Manual: A Guide to Cost-Effective<br />

Sustainable Public Procurement, 2 nd Edition, Available:<br />

http://www.procuraplus.com/fileadmin/template/projects/procuraplus/New_website/Printed_Manual<br />

/Procura__Manual_complete.pdf


57.2 Benefits <strong>of</strong> Green Procurement<br />

In total, public authorities across Europe have the purchasing power equivalent to a<br />

16% share <strong>of</strong> the EU’s gross domestic product, amounting to almost €2,000 billion<br />

per year. 1054 This vast sum <strong>of</strong> money is commonly spent within sectors which have<br />

relatively high environmental impacts, for example, construction, waste management,<br />

transport and energy.<br />

The significant market leverage force held by public authorities can influence<br />

suppliers, and innovation and production, <strong>of</strong> ‘greener’ products and services. 1055 The<br />

force <strong>of</strong> public procurement may have the capacity to reduce the unit costs through<br />

increasing demand for ‘greener’ products. Furthermore, this has the potential to<br />

influence the behaviour and consumption habits <strong>of</strong> the private sector and general<br />

public when purchasing good and services, not least by enhancing the availability <strong>of</strong><br />

product information.<br />

Reducing the environmental impact <strong>of</strong> the public sector, and potential improvements<br />

this may have upon procurement within the private sector, are expected to result in<br />

reduced carbon emissions, reduced waste and increased water efficiency. These<br />

environmental impacts will <strong>of</strong>ten help to meet various national and European<br />

environmental targets which have been agreed.<br />

57.3 Regulatory Framework<br />

In the past, concerns were raised regarding potential problems, including distortion <strong>of</strong><br />

the single market and reduction <strong>of</strong> competition within the EU, as the uptake <strong>of</strong> Green<br />

Public Procurement policies increased across Member States. The need for continuity<br />

in policies from country to country led to the development <strong>of</strong> the EU regulatory<br />

framework as it stands today, which is shown in Figure 57-1. This framework has<br />

developed under the Treaty <strong>of</strong> the Amsterdam in 1997, in which sustainable<br />

development became a fundamental objective; the 2001 Gothenburg Summit, which<br />

launched the first EU sustainable development strategy; and the 2002 World Summit<br />

on Sustainable Development in Johannesburg, during which a Plan <strong>of</strong> Implementation<br />

was agreed stating that all relevant authorities at all levels should,<br />

847<br />

“promote public procurement policies that encourage development and<br />

diffusion <strong>of</strong> environmentally sound goods and service.” 1056<br />

1054 European Commission (2008) Quote from Stavros Dimas, EU Commissioner for Environment,<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/background_en.htm<br />

1055 Öko-Institut and Iclei (2007) Costs and Benefits <strong>of</strong> Green Public Procurement in Europe, Available:<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/index_en.htm .<br />

1056 IDeA Procurement (2003) Sustainability and Local Government Procurement, Improvement and<br />

Development Agency for Local Government, Available: http://www.idea.gov.uk/idk/aio/1701515<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 57-1: EU Regulatory Framework<br />

848<br />

29/09/09<br />

Year <strong>Policy</strong> / Strategy Summary <strong>of</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>/Strategy Objective(s)<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2006<br />

2008<br />

Commission Communication on<br />

Integrated Product <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Directive 2004/17/EC: to<br />

coordinate the procurement<br />

procedures <strong>of</strong> entities<br />

operating in the water, energy,<br />

transport and postal services<br />

sectors<br />

Directive 2004/18/EC: to<br />

coordinate the procedures for<br />

the award <strong>of</strong> public works<br />

contracts, public supply<br />

contracts and public service<br />

contracts<br />

EU Sustainable Development<br />

Strategy<br />

Action Plan on Sustainable<br />

Consumption and Production<br />

and Sustainable Industrial<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> (SCP/SIP)<br />

Training Toolkit on Green Public<br />

Procurement<br />

Renewed EU Sustainable<br />

Development Strategy<br />

Member States recommended to adopt<br />

national plans for GPP by the end <strong>of</strong><br />

March 2006<br />

Clarified how public purchasers can<br />

include environmental considerations<br />

into their procurement procedures. This<br />

is explained in the ‘Buying Green! -<br />

Handbook on Green Public Procurement’<br />

Set the policy objective for 2010 <strong>of</strong><br />

bringing the average level <strong>of</strong> EU GPP up<br />

to the standard achieved by the best<br />

performing Member States in 2006.<br />

Series <strong>of</strong> communiciations which aim to<br />

develop and set environmental criteria in<br />

greater detail for potential use for GPP.<br />

Defines criteria which have been<br />

developed for product and service groups<br />

in the 10 sectors that are thought to be<br />

most suitable for implementing GPP.<br />

Set the policy objective for Member<br />

States to have 50% GPP by 2010.<br />

As shown explicitly in Figure 57-1, in 2004 the two Directives (Directive 2004/17/EC<br />

and Directive 2004/18/EC) allowed public authorities to include environmental<br />

priorities within their procurement process. The Directives, and supporting<br />

documents, show how environmental criteria can be introduced, whilst ensuring the<br />

internal market functions correctly allowing for free movement <strong>of</strong> good and services,<br />

equal treatment <strong>of</strong> bidders and best value for money is achieved.<br />

One supporting document, the EU’s ‘Green Procurement Guide’, provides practical<br />

advice on how to implement environmental measures within a contract, in line with<br />

European legislation. Table 57-1 is not exhaustive but it provides some examples <strong>of</strong>


what can, and what cannot be done, when including environmental criteria within a<br />

contract.<br />

Table 57-1: Limitations to the Inclusion <strong>of</strong> Environmental Criteria within a Contract<br />

849<br />

Topic Topic Topic<br />

You You can… can…<br />

You You cannot…<br />

cannot…<br />

Subject Matter <strong>of</strong> a Contract<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

...freely define the subject <strong>of</strong><br />

the contract.<br />

…specify using technical<br />

standards or on performance<br />

based requirements.<br />

…define specific products or<br />

services since this may<br />

distort the level playing-field.<br />

…require tenderers to be<br />

registered under a certain<br />

eco-label scheme.<br />

Technical Specifications E.g. Using EU eco-labels for light bulbs: The EU eco-label<br />

criteria for light bulbs require that they should have an<br />

average life-span <strong>of</strong> 10 000 hours. When reflecting this in a<br />

call for tender for light bulbs, 10 000 hours could be set as<br />

the technical specification for the minimum life span. 1057<br />

Technical Standards<br />

Material Requirements<br />

Process Requirements<br />

Process Requirements<br />

Examples<br />

…define a higher level <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental protection<br />

than laid down in a standard.<br />

…insist that the product you<br />

are purchasing is made from<br />

a specified material.<br />

…include requirements on<br />

production methods in the<br />

specifications for green<br />

procurement.<br />

…e.g. ask for electricity<br />

produced from renewable<br />

energy sources<br />

…define a higher level <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental protection<br />

than laid down in a standard<br />

that discriminates against<br />

potential bidders.<br />

…breach the principles <strong>of</strong><br />

non-discrimination, and the<br />

free movement <strong>of</strong> goods and<br />

services.<br />

…include requirements which<br />

are not related to the<br />

manufacturing <strong>of</strong> the<br />

product, or which don’t<br />

contribute to its<br />

characteristics.<br />

…e.g. require a company<br />

from whom you are<br />

purchasing furniture to use<br />

recycled paper in their <strong>of</strong>fices<br />

In 2008, ten priority sectors were identified by the Commission in the Training Toolkit<br />

on Green Public Procurement. These were based on the following:<br />

� scope for environmental improvement;<br />

1057 European Commission (2004) Buying Green! – A Handbook on Environmental Public Procurement,<br />

Available: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/buying_green_handbook_en.pdf


850<br />

29/09/09<br />

� public expenditure;<br />

� potential impact on the supply side;<br />

� example setting for private or corporate consumers;<br />

� political sensitivity;<br />

� existence <strong>of</strong> relevant and easy-to-use criteria (e.g. current eco-labelling);<br />

� market availability; and<br />

� economic efficiency. 1058<br />

The priority sectors are:<br />

1. Construction;<br />

2. Food and catering services;<br />

3. Transport and transport services;<br />

4. Energy;<br />

5. Office machinery and computers;<br />

6. Clothing, uniforms and other textiles;<br />

7. Paper and printing services;<br />

8. Furniture;<br />

9. Cleaning products and services; and<br />

10. Equipment used in the health sector. 1059<br />

The current legislative framework has resulted in a non-binding target <strong>of</strong> 50% for the<br />

average level <strong>of</strong> Green Public Procurement in each Member State from 2010,<br />

progress towards which will be monitored using the methodology proposed by the<br />

consortia <strong>of</strong> PricewaterhouseCoopers, Significant and Ec<strong>of</strong>ys published in January<br />

2009. 1060<br />

1058 European Commission (2008) Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament,<br />

the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee <strong>of</strong> the Regions: Public<br />

Procurement for a Better Environment, Available: http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2008:0400:FIN:EN:PDF<br />

1059 European Commission (2008) Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament,<br />

the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee <strong>of</strong> the Regions: Public<br />

Procurement for a Better Environment, Available: http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2008:0400:FIN:EN:PDF<br />

1060 PricewaterhouseCoopers, Significant and Ec<strong>of</strong>ys (2009) Collection <strong>of</strong> Statistical Information on<br />

Green Public Procurement in the EU: Report on Data Collection Results, Available:<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/statistical_information.pdf


In light <strong>of</strong> the renewed EU Sustainable Development Strategy several Member States<br />

adopted ambitious green and sustainable procurement targets across a range <strong>of</strong><br />

priority sectors. 1061<br />

57.4 Government Influence towards Green Procurement<br />

Despite the propensity for environmental criteria to be included within public<br />

procurement at an increasing rate, Ireland has shown comparatively limited progress.<br />

Their absence from the ‘National Sources’ section <strong>of</strong> the European Commission’s<br />

Green Public Procurement website is notable, along with the lack <strong>of</strong> progress<br />

regarding their Action Plan for Green Procurement. 1062 In 2007, Ireland’s National<br />

Climate Change Strategy stated that,<br />

851<br />

“The Government will publish its Action Plan for Green Public Procurement in<br />

2007,” 1063<br />

Despite this claim it is still being drafted.<br />

Within the current legislative framework European governments can be hugely<br />

influential. Through adoption <strong>of</strong> the EU targets, outlined in a national action plan, they<br />

can lead the way towards the ‘greening’ <strong>of</strong> their public sector. In order to encourage<br />

adoption across local government and other public bodies, central government can<br />

produce guidance and information. This should inform the procurement <strong>of</strong>ficers with<br />

all the information they need to confidently include environmental specifications<br />

within a call to tender.<br />

For example, the UK adopted a ‘Sustainable Procurement Action Plan’ which is<br />

enforced via target-setting. The targets apply to all central Government <strong>Department</strong>s,<br />

executive agencies and Non-<strong>Department</strong>al Public Bodies (in the majority <strong>of</strong> cases)<br />

and have been effective since 2006. This replaced the ‘Framework for Sustainable<br />

Development on the Government Estate’. In 2003, national policy filtered down to<br />

local government in the ‘National Procurement Strategy for Local Government in<br />

England (2003-2006)’.<br />

Many green procurement processes target emissions, but equally examples can be<br />

found which affect the waste management sector. For example, for construction and<br />

demolition projects the targets set can influence recycling and reuse rates on site,<br />

and minimum recycled content requirements for the materials used.<br />

Four waste related examples follow in Section 57.4.1 to Section 57.4.7.<br />

1061 The Dutch government has set a 100% Sustainable Procurement target for 2010 and the Austrian<br />

government has set targets by priority sector including 95% for IT, 80% for electricity, 30% for paper,<br />

95% for cleaning products and 20% for vehicles.<br />

1062 European Commission (2009) Green Public Procurement Website: Useful Sources <strong>of</strong> Guidance<br />

and Information, Available: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/guideline_en.htm<br />

1063 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government (2007) Ireland: National Climate<br />

Change Strategy 2007 – 2012, Available:<br />

http://www.environ.ie/en/PublicationsDocuments/FileDownLoad,1861,en.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


57.4.1 UK Public Sector<br />

Central Central Central Government<br />

Government<br />

Across the Government there is a hierarchy <strong>of</strong> support for the development and<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> green procurement policy. This includes Defra, responsible for<br />

developing green procurement policy across Government departments, the Chief<br />

Sustainability Officer and the Centre <strong>of</strong> Expertise in Sustainable Procurement at the<br />

Office <strong>of</strong> Government Commerce. These groups are guided by the Sustainable<br />

Development Commission who act as an independent watchdog.<br />

In 2005 the Government’s sustainable development strategy set the ambitious goal<br />

<strong>of</strong> becoming a sustainable procurement leader amongst EU member states by 2009.<br />

This was followed by a Sustainable Procurement Action Plan published in 2007 and<br />

most recently a Delivery Plan in 2008.<br />

A main issue with the Government’s strategy is the lack <strong>of</strong> measurability. There is not<br />

one single quantified goal, just the statement regarding leadership within the EU.<br />

Progress is measured against a series <strong>of</strong> initiatives which include:<br />

852<br />

29/09/09<br />

� The Framework for Sustainable Operations on the Government Estate;<br />

� Sustainable Procurement Action Plan;<br />

� Quick Wins standards; and<br />

� The Sustainable Procurement Task Force’s Flexible Framework.<br />

The most recent progress report, ‘Addressing the Environmental Impacts <strong>of</strong><br />

Government Procurement’ focused on four main procurement categories which were<br />

energy, information and communications technology, <strong>of</strong>fice supplies and services and<br />

vehicle fleets. The report covers five areas <strong>of</strong> government which account for a high<br />

percentage <strong>of</strong> the Government’s overall expenditure which are the <strong>Department</strong> for<br />

Work and Pensions (DWP), HM Revenue and Customs, Ministry <strong>of</strong> Defence, Ministry<br />

<strong>of</strong> Justice and the health service. 1064<br />

The main findings from the National Audit Office’s progress report suggest that <strong>of</strong> the<br />

five departments investigated only the National Health Service Purchasing and Supply<br />

Agency (NHS PASA) are reaching the required level <strong>of</strong> sustainable procurement a year<br />

in advance <strong>of</strong> the requirement, according to the Sustainable Procurement Task<br />

Force’s Flexible Framework. The DWP are also on target to fulfil this goal but the other<br />

three departments are,<br />

‘some way from having embedded sustainable procurement into their working<br />

practices’. 1065<br />

1064 National Audit Office (2009) Addressing the Environmental Impacts <strong>of</strong> Government Procurement,<br />

Available: http://www.nao.org.uk//idoc.ashx?docId=56417d76-45d6-4181-916cda4c00b1bc88&version=-1<br />

1065 National Audit Office (2009) Addressing the Environmental Impacts <strong>of</strong> Government Procurement,<br />

Available: http://www.nao.org.uk//idoc.ashx?docId=56417d76-45d6-4181-916cda4c00b1bc88&version=-1


WRAP WRAP<br />

WRAP<br />

The greening <strong>of</strong> service procurement has arisen through inclusion <strong>of</strong> recycled paper<br />

requirements for the tender. The attitude surrounding presentation <strong>of</strong> project bids has<br />

changed in recent years – with a shift away from wasteful printing. This is exemplified<br />

by a tender invitation published by WRAP in March 2009 which is typical <strong>of</strong> all WRAP<br />

tenders in that it states,<br />

853<br />

‘Your tender submission should be printed double sided, submitted on<br />

recycled paper wherever possible and should be limited to no more than 20<br />

pages (excluding appendices)’. 1066<br />

Craigavon Craigavon Borough Borough Council<br />

Council<br />

Craigavon Borough Council has a Green Procurement <strong>Policy</strong>, implemented by their<br />

Purchasing Group, which aims to reduce their overall environmental impact.<br />

Craigavon, along with the Greater London Authority and York, is one <strong>of</strong> the only three<br />

UK participants in the <strong>International</strong> Procura+ Sustainable Procurement Campaign. 1067<br />

Some examples <strong>of</strong> how waste-related issues have been included with Craigavon’s<br />

GPP are as follows: 1068<br />

Compost<br />

Compost<br />

Craigavon Borough Council specify that with regards to compost and mulch<br />

preference should be given,<br />

‘to those produced from regionally generated plant debris and/or food waste’<br />

Recycled Recycled Content Content Products<br />

Products<br />

‘Products that contain recycled content, particularly post consumer content,<br />

are to be prioritised.’<br />

Small Small Small Consumables<br />

Consumables<br />

Tenders<br />

Tenders<br />

‘GPP requirements will apply to each <strong>of</strong> the products through the use <strong>of</strong> the<br />

procurement s<strong>of</strong>tware. Purchasing criteria and guidelines on small<br />

consumables will be stored on a database, along with relevant order<br />

information on each product.’<br />

‘To demonstrate our commitment to ensuring that companies providing<br />

services to Craigavon Borough Council are in compliance with environmental<br />

regulations and are taking additional steps to conserve resources, prevent<br />

pollution and minimize waste, suppliers and contractors wishing to provide<br />

1066 WRAP (2009) Tender Invitation Document: EVA123-000 Landfill Bans Research.<br />

1067 Procura+ is an initiative designed to help support public authorities in implementing Sustainable<br />

Procurement, Website available: http://www.procuraplus.org/index.php?id=4594<br />

1068 Craigavon Borough Council (1999) Green Procurement <strong>Policy</strong>, Available:<br />

http://www.procuraplus.org/fileadmin/template/projects/procuraplus/files/tenders___NAP/Craigavon<br />

_Green_Procurement_<strong>Policy</strong>_2007.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


854<br />

29/09/09<br />

services should be encourages to become certified by some environmental<br />

standard.’<br />

57.4.2 Japan’s Green Purchasing Law<br />

The Green Purchasing Law, which came into force in 2001, stipulates the<br />

requirement for the Japanese Government and national public organisations to<br />

promote green procurement. This is supported via a green purchasing guideline which<br />

catalogues several hundred green products and which is updated annually; a Green<br />

Purchasing Network which disseminates information; and an ‘Eco-product’ exposition<br />

which is held each year. The promotion <strong>of</strong> green procurement is reinforced by an<br />

annual reporting requirement to the Ministry <strong>of</strong> the Environment. 1069 The increasing<br />

share <strong>of</strong> green products since the year the policy was implemented is shown in Figure<br />

57-2.<br />

Figure 57-2: Green Purchasing by the Japanese Government and National Institutions<br />

(excluding Public Works)<br />

Source: Tananka,R. (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction in Japan, British Embassy Tokyo, Available:<br />

http://ukinjapanstage.fco.gov.uk/resources/en/pdf/5606907/5633507/071030<strong>Waste</strong>Reduction.pdf<br />

1069 R. Tananka (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction in Japan, British Embassy Tokyo, Available: http://ukinjapanstage.fco.gov.uk/resources/en/pdf/5606907/5633507/071030<strong>Waste</strong>Reduction.pdf


57.4.3 Washington State Recycling and Conservation Paper Law<br />

In May 2009 Washington adopted a paper recycling and conservation law which<br />

requires state agencies and colleges, with buildings with 25 or more employees, to:<br />

855<br />

� purchase 100% recycled content printing paper;<br />

� reduce printing paper use by 30% before July 2010;<br />

� recycle 100% printing paper;<br />

� restrict future leases/purchase <strong>of</strong> printers and copiers to those which<br />

efficiently use 100% recycled content paper; and<br />

� prioritise purchasing from companies that produce paper in mills powered<br />

by renewable energy. 1070<br />

57.4.4 The Scottish Executive<br />

In 2006 the Scottish Executive requested all Scottish public authorities to ensure that<br />

at least 10% <strong>of</strong> the total value <strong>of</strong> materials used on projects worth over £1m should<br />

be derived from reused or recycled materials. In addition minimum recycled content<br />

levels were set for paper products (50% for printing paper and 100% in tissue<br />

paper). 1071<br />

57.4.5 The Olympic Delivery Authority<br />

In preparation for the 2012 Olympics the Olympic Delivery Authority are undertaking<br />

major construction works. Their Sustainable Development Strategy has set the<br />

minimum requirement <strong>of</strong> 90%, by weight, <strong>of</strong> the material arising through demolition<br />

works to be reused or recycled. 1072<br />

57.4.6 Newport Southern Distributor Road<br />

This project involved road improvement to a dual carriageway in Newport, South<br />

Wales. This case study was used by Defra to undertake a cost-benefit analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

project. 1073 The project, funded under a Private Finance Initiative (PFI) contract,<br />

1070 State <strong>of</strong> Washington <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Ecology (2009) New Law Makes State’s Paper Usage Leaner,<br />

Greener, News Release 6 th May 2009, Available: http://www.ecy.wa.gov/news/2009news/2009-<br />

103.html<br />

1071 Edie News (2006) Scottish Institutions Set Green Procurement Targets, Available:<br />

http://www.edie.net/news/news_story.asp?id=12368&channel=0<br />

1072 Olympic Delivery Authority (2007) Sustainable Development Strategy, Available:<br />

http://www.london2012.com/documents/oda-publications/oda-sustainable-development-strategy-fullversion.pdf<br />

1073 SQW Ltd (2006) Cost Benefit Analysis <strong>of</strong> Sustainable Public Procurement, Final Report to DEFRA,<br />

Available:<br />

http://randd.defra.gov.uk/Default.aspx?Menu=Menu&Module=More&Location=None&ProjectID=140<br />

62&FromSearch=Y&Publisher=1&SearchText=EP01024%20&SortString=ProjectCode&SortOrder=Asc<br />

&Paging=10<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


sought to utilise locally available recyclable materials. In using steel slag, available<br />

from the former steelworks in the area, and material from the nearby rail recycling<br />

depot, they used 97.5% recycled aggregate which resulted in a direct cost saving <strong>of</strong><br />

just over £1 million, mainly due to savings made from avoiding the aggregate tax.<br />

Further savings were made through avoided carbon emissions since by using locally<br />

sourced aggregate, haulage distances were reduced; recycling material generated onsite<br />

led to reduced landfill disposal costs and reduced carbon emissions; and health<br />

benefits were identified through less transportation. The total savings equated to<br />

3.82% <strong>of</strong> project costs.<br />

57.4.7 Mayor <strong>of</strong> London’s Green Procurement Code<br />

The Mayor <strong>of</strong> London’s Green Procurement Code is a support service which has been<br />

set up for London based organisations. Having committed to the Green Procurement<br />

Code, organisations receive a green procurement toolkit with advice and information.<br />

A progress review encourages organisations to strive to achieve progressive<br />

environmental targets which are awarded with gold, silver and bronze certifications.<br />

The service was launched in 2001 and since then members <strong>of</strong> the Green<br />

Procurement Code have collectively diverted 1.3 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste from landfill.<br />

In 2006, 175,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> carbon dioxide was saved which is equivalent to yearly<br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> over 29,000 households. 1074 In truth, it may be that some <strong>of</strong> this would<br />

have happened anyway, since these figures relate to organisations signing up to the<br />

Code.<br />

57.5 Scope for Green Public Procurement in Ireland<br />

With respect to Ireland, the EU regulatory framework is highly relevant in setting the<br />

scene and realising the scope for green public procurement. However, it is worth<br />

noting that the EU is currently lagging behind the USA, Canada and Japan who have<br />

all mandated green public procurement in various forms. 1075<br />

In 2006 work undertaken for the European Commission highlighted the top seven<br />

countries undertaking a significant level <strong>of</strong> Green Public Procurement, <strong>of</strong> which<br />

Ireland was not one. 1076 The ‘Green 7’ are Austria, Denmark, Finland, Germany,<br />

Netherlands, Sweden and the UK. However, even within these countries many <strong>of</strong> the<br />

tenders were found not to be fully compliant with EU procurement law. At the<br />

beginning <strong>of</strong> 2008, Ireland was not one <strong>of</strong> the 14 Member States that had adopted a<br />

national action plan for their Green Public Procurement, despite the Commission’s<br />

1074 Mayor <strong>of</strong> London’s Green Procurement Code (2009) Information taken from the website:<br />

http://www.greenprocurementcode.co.uk/<br />

1075 European Commission (2008) Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament,<br />

the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee <strong>of</strong> the Regions: Public<br />

Procurement for a Better Environment Impact Assessment, Available:<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/sec_2008_2124_EN.pdf<br />

1076 M. Bouwer, M. Jonk, P. Szuppinger, H. Lusser, T. Berman, R. Bersani, V. Nappa, C. Vigano, A.<br />

Nissinen and K. Parikka (2006) Green Public Procurement, Report to the European Commission,<br />

Available: http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/report_facts.pdf<br />

856<br />

29/09/09


ecommendation to do so in 2003 via the Communication on Integrated Public<br />

<strong>Policy</strong>. 1077<br />

Ireland’s National Climate Change Strategy 2007-2012 states the following with<br />

regards to procurement,<br />

857<br />

“The Government will publish its Action Plan for Green Public Procurement in<br />

2007” 1078<br />

Despite this claim, Ireland has started work on their draft national action plan but to<br />

date their current Green Public Procurement relevant legislation is:<br />

� Green Government Guide (1996) which recommends green public<br />

purchasing; and<br />

� <strong>Policy</strong> Statement on Recycling and Preventing <strong>Waste</strong> (2002) which<br />

recommend use <strong>of</strong> recycled and recyclable materials in GPP. 1079<br />

The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government’s website has a<br />

small section on GPP located on the ‘Sustainable Development’ webpage. 1080 The<br />

text is copied into Box 1 below and highlights the need for national legislation to be<br />

developed. The national government cannot rely upon local authorities to adopt, and<br />

take forward, European Guidelines. There is likely to be a need for leadership, and<br />

possibly, binding targets, alongside information to guide central government, its<br />

agencies and local authorities to demonstrate how implementation <strong>of</strong> GPP can be<br />

made straightforward, and how to realise the benefits <strong>of</strong> GPP.<br />

In order to confirm the <strong>Department</strong>’s commitment to green procurement the following<br />

two questions, and subsequent answers, were put to the Minister for the<br />

Environment:<br />

1. Q: To ask the Minister for the Environment, Heritage and<br />

Local Government the reason Ireland has not adopted a national action<br />

plan for green public procurement despite the fact that such a plan was<br />

required to be adopted by the end <strong>of</strong> 2006; and if he will make a<br />

statement on the matter.<br />

1077 European Commission (2008) Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament,<br />

the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee <strong>of</strong> the Regions: Public<br />

Procurement for a Better Environment Impact Assessment, Available:<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/sec_2008_2124_EN.pdf<br />

1078 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government (2007) Ireland: National Climate<br />

Change Strategy 2007 – 2012, Available:<br />

http://www.environ.ie/en/PublicationsDocuments/FileDownLoad,1861,en.pdf<br />

1079 European Commission (2008) Guide to National GPP Policies and Guidelines, Available:<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/national_gpp_strategies_en.pdf<br />

1080 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government (2009) Sustainable Development<br />

web page, Available: http://www.environ.ie/en/Environment/SustainableDevelopment/<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


858<br />

29/09/09<br />

A: “The conclusions adopted by the September 2008 EU Competitiveness<br />

Council recalled the aim <strong>of</strong> the EU Sustainable Development Strategy on<br />

Green Public Procurement and provided a comprehensive overview <strong>of</strong><br />

developments and commitments.<br />

The Government’s commitment to green public procurement was<br />

confirmed in the 2008 Framework For Sustainable Economic Renewal<br />

Building Ireland’s Smart Economy. My <strong>Department</strong> is committed to the<br />

preparation <strong>of</strong> an action plan on green public procurement. In doing so, we<br />

will work with the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Finance’s National Public Procurement<br />

<strong>Policy</strong> Unit which has overall responsibility for public procurement policy in<br />

Ireland.”<br />

Box Box Box 1: 1: Green Green Public Public Procurement Procurement 1081<br />

In Ireland, the total Government and public sector purchasing budget is over €10 billion per<br />

annum. If purchasers in the public sector consistently specified environmentally<br />

advantageous criteria in their specifications, it would provide significant leverage to “move<br />

the market” towards the economic provision <strong>of</strong> environmentally superior goods and services.<br />

The Government is therefore committed to promoting Green Public Procurement (GPP).<br />

The National Public Procurement <strong>Policy</strong> Unit (NPPPU) <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Finance has<br />

overall responsibility for public procurement policy in Ireland. NPPPU maintains the website<br />

http://www.etenders.gov.ie/, a centralised portal containing comprehensive information on<br />

public procurement. Sustainable Development Unit has the lead role in “greening”<br />

procurement across the public sector. We therefore liaise closely with NPPPU on highlighting<br />

information on http://www.etenders.gov.ie/ on how to integrate environmental<br />

considerations into purchasing practices for goods and services. This includes the EU<br />

Handbook on Environmental Public Procurement.<br />

The Procura Plus Manual, published by ICLEI Local Governments for Sustainability, is a very<br />

practical and useful guide to cost-effective public procurement. It includes international<br />

examples and case studies from a variety <strong>of</strong> organisations in the public sector.<br />

The European Commission maintains a dedicated website on Green Public Procurement. This<br />

includes information on Member States’ National Action Plans on GPP, envisaged as part <strong>of</strong><br />

the implementation <strong>of</strong> the EU Environmental Technologies Action Plan (ETAP). Sustainable<br />

Development Unit is currently preparing Ireland’s National Action Plan on GPP.<br />

2. Q: To ask the Minister for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government<br />

the action proposed to ensure that the EU sustainable strategy in respect<br />

<strong>of</strong> green procurement targets will be met; and if he will make a statement<br />

on the matter.<br />

A: “We will also work with the National Procurement Operations Unit in the<br />

Office <strong>of</strong> Public Works. The new Unit will be a centre <strong>of</strong> excellence for<br />

public procurement generally and will facilitate the integration <strong>of</strong> whole-<strong>of</strong>-<br />

Government policy issues in areas such as sustainability and the<br />

1081 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Heritage and Local Government (2009) Sustainable Development<br />

web page, Available: http://www.environ.ie/en/Environment/SustainableDevelopment/


859<br />

environment into public procurement practice for the organisations served<br />

by the Unit.”<br />

The Market Development Programme (MDP) is now involved in this process. The MDP<br />

Action Plan states: 1082<br />

The <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Finance is committed to the further integration <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental considerations into the public procurement process in 2009,<br />

with the goal <strong>of</strong> bringing us into line with the best performers in Europe. In this<br />

regard, the National Operations Unit (NOU) has been established by the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Finance in order to achieve efficiency and value for money<br />

through the use <strong>of</strong> centralised and specialised procurement, allowing all<br />

central Government <strong>Department</strong>s and Offices, agencies and non-commercial<br />

bodies to acquire a range <strong>of</strong> goods and services more effectively and<br />

efficiently.<br />

The Market Development Programme will co-operate with the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

Finance in promoting Green Procurement. In addition, the Implementation<br />

Team will collaborate on Green Procurement with the DOEHLG, other<br />

Government <strong>Department</strong>s and Agencies, the Forfás High Level Action Group<br />

on Green Enterprise as well as key stakeholder groups like the EU, EPA and<br />

local authorities who have already started delivering best practice and tools in<br />

this area. Working together will avoid duplication <strong>of</strong> efforts and ensure that<br />

optimal and consistent Green Procurement strategies are put in place across<br />

the different sectors and organisations.<br />

The goals <strong>of</strong> the Market Development Programme are stated as:<br />

� Identify and overcome challenges to Green Procurement in the use <strong>of</strong><br />

materials produced by the recycling <strong>of</strong> organic, paper, plastic and other waste<br />

materials,<br />

� Provide information on the availability and suppliers <strong>of</strong> green products,<br />

� Promote the development <strong>of</strong> Green Procurement policies in public and private<br />

sectors,<br />

� Demonstrate the economic and environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> Green Procurement<br />

policies within public and private sectors,<br />

� Provide information to the public and private sectors on the practical aspects<br />

<strong>of</strong> Green Procurement.<br />

It is to be hoped that this will add some impetus to the process, although the above<br />

goals suggest that the MDP’s role will be supportive rather than leading on policy<br />

development. Critical in the process will be the commitment <strong>of</strong> high level <strong>of</strong>ficials in<br />

Government, notably in the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Finance and in DoEHLG, to carry the<br />

process forward with vigour. The slowness <strong>of</strong> progress thus far suggests that in the<br />

past, this has been absent, with words uttered, but little by way <strong>of</strong> action taken.<br />

1082 Market Development Programme (2009) Market Development Programme for <strong>Waste</strong> and<br />

Resources, Action Plan 2009.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


57.5.1 Barriers to Uptake <strong>of</strong> Green Public Procurement<br />

The European Commission’s ‘Public Procurement for a Better Environment: Impact<br />

Assessment’ details specific problems and barriers which are known to hinder the<br />

uptake <strong>of</strong> green public procurement. They are listed below, but further details can be<br />

found in the source document:<br />

860<br />

29/09/09<br />

1. Lack <strong>of</strong> awareness <strong>of</strong> benefits, misperception <strong>of</strong> the extent <strong>of</strong> costs, and<br />

lack <strong>of</strong> political priority for GPP;<br />

2. Legal problems;<br />

3. Lack <strong>of</strong> information and tools for GPP, inadequate training structures, lack<br />

<strong>of</strong> knowledge <strong>of</strong> priority areas and absence <strong>of</strong> easy to apply GPP criteria;<br />

and<br />

4. A lack <strong>of</strong> similarity between GPP procedures and criteria across the EU.<br />

It is also felt that perceived legal problems, and general misperception over the scale<br />

<strong>of</strong> the green procurement implementation process, hinder the take up <strong>of</strong> such a<br />

policy. 1083<br />

57.5.2 Administrative Costs<br />

Green procurement leads to consideration <strong>of</strong> a product or service’s whole life costs.<br />

The overall saving made through implementation <strong>of</strong> GPP depends on the<br />

administrative costs involved, and whether or not they <strong>of</strong>fset the savings. A report to<br />

Defra in 2006, which undertook a cost benefit analysis on sustainable public<br />

procurement, found evidence to suggest that savings are made over time when the<br />

GPP process has been established and administrative tasks have been integrated.<br />

This means that the majority <strong>of</strong> associated costs are ‘one-<strong>of</strong>f’ and once embedded<br />

into the system they can begin to deliver value. As policy implementation internalises<br />

environmental performance (emissions trading etc.) then Green Procurement starts<br />

to become more cost-effective.<br />

Administrative costs will depend on the current procurement processes in place, and<br />

how these are managed. On average, individual authorities who are setting up and<br />

implementing GPP spend a total <strong>of</strong> €223/1000 inhabitants over 2-6 years. 1084<br />

57.6 Conclusions<br />

In light <strong>of</strong> the European framework which is in place, Member States ought to be<br />

striving to reach the target <strong>of</strong> 50% for the average level <strong>of</strong> green public procurement<br />

by 2010. This target seems unlikely to be met by Ireland, and there is not yet any<br />

formalised commitment to this as far as we are aware. The formalised EU framework<br />

1083 National Audit Office (2009) Addressing the Environmental Impacts <strong>of</strong> Government Procurement,<br />

Available: http://www.nao.org.uk//idoc.ashx?docId=56417d76-45d6-4181-916cda4c00b1bc88&version=-1<br />

1084 Oko-Institut (2007) Costs and Benefits <strong>of</strong> Green Public Procurement in Europe, Available:<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/gpp/pdf/eu_recommendations_2.pdf


has created a ‘level playing field’ in which the potential issues <strong>of</strong> barriers to trade<br />

have been largely resolved.<br />

In Ireland the framework requires formalising through production <strong>of</strong> a finalised<br />

national action plan. This should go above and beyond the influence <strong>of</strong> the current<br />

sustainable consumption and production initiatives which are in place. Failing to<br />

formally adopt a green public procurement policy may hinder product innovation and<br />

eco-design and availability <strong>of</strong> environmentally sound services. In the area <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management, it essentially implies a failure to ‘close the loop’ to the extent that those<br />

who recycle might not be using the power <strong>of</strong> public purchasing to help increase<br />

demand for secondary materials, and hence, the viability <strong>of</strong> the industry which leads<br />

to their production.<br />

861<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


58.0 Ireland and the UNECE / Stockholm<br />

Conventions<br />

Irish waste management (and other) policy should incorporate measures to ensure<br />

compliance with both the UNECE and Stockholm Conventions (see Annex 1.0). This<br />

requirement may be not be immediately obvious because whilst Ireland is a signatory<br />

to both the UNECE and the Stockholm conventions, it is not a party to either. 1085 The<br />

EU, however, is a party to both and has implemented them through regulations which<br />

also apply to Ireland. The main legal instrument for implementing the Stockholm<br />

Convention and the UNECE Protocol on POPs within the EU is Regulation (EC) No.<br />

850/2004. 1086 This Regulation entered into force 20 th May 2004 and as a<br />

regulation, it is directly applicable in all Member States, including those, like Ireland,<br />

which are not yet Parties in their own right to the Stockholm Convention or the UNECE<br />

Protocols. Two separate Council decisions concerning the Community’s conclusions<br />

on these two international agreements have been made in parallel to the<br />

Regulation. 1087 Ireland should, therefore, have implemented these requirements<br />

already and should be ensuring compliance with the Stockholm Convention<br />

obligations. At present, there is no obvious evidence that this has been done in<br />

practice, though a National Implementation Plan (NIP) is in the process <strong>of</strong> being<br />

prepared (see below).<br />

The EPA has been designated by the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage and Local<br />

Government as the Competent Authority for the implementation and enforcement in<br />

Ireland <strong>of</strong> Regulation 850/2004 on POPs. 1088 The EPA liaises with relevant public<br />

bodies such as, Food Safety Authority <strong>of</strong> Ireland, Irish Medicines Board, Health and<br />

Safety Authority and Pesticide Control Service to regulate POPs in Ireland.<br />

Article 8 <strong>of</strong> the same Regulation - 850/2004 - is the legal basis for the requirement to<br />

prepare a NIP. This is currently being prepared in Ireland, as described above<br />

1085 Ireland signed the Stockholm Convention on 23 rd May 2001 but has not yet ratified.<br />

http://chm.pops.int/Countries/Status<strong>of</strong>Ratification/tabid/252/language/en-US/Default.aspx<br />

1086 European Commission (2004) Regulation (EC) No 850/2004 Of The European Parliament and <strong>of</strong><br />

the Council <strong>of</strong> 29 April 2004 on persistent organic pollutants and amending Directive 79/117/EEC<br />

Note that whilst this was published in the Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Union L158 <strong>of</strong> 30th April<br />

2004, a Corrigendum to the Regulation was subsequently published in the Official Journal L229/5 <strong>of</strong><br />

29th June 2004. 2004, Official Journal <strong>of</strong> the European Union L 229/5.<br />

1087 Council Decision 259/2004/EC <strong>of</strong> 19 February 2004 concerning the conclusion, on behalf <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European Community, <strong>of</strong> the Protocol to the 1979 Convention on Long Range Transboundary Air<br />

Pollution on Persistent Organic Pollutants; and Council Decision concerning the conclusion, on behalf<br />

<strong>of</strong> the European Community, <strong>of</strong> the Stockholm Convention on Persistent Organic Pollutants was<br />

adopted on 14 October 2004.<br />

1088 Environmental Protection Agency (2008) Consultation Paper on a Proposal to Prepare a National<br />

Implementation Plan on Persistent Organic Pollutants, June 2008.<br />

862<br />

29/09/09


Article 6 <strong>of</strong> Regulation (EC) No.850/2004 requires:<br />

863<br />

3. Member States shall, when considering proposals to construct new<br />

facilities or significantly to modify existing facilities using processes that<br />

release chemicals listed in Annex III, without prejudice to Council Directive<br />

1996/61/EC (1), give priority consideration to alternative processes,<br />

techniques or practices that have similar usefulness but which avoid the<br />

formation and release <strong>of</strong> substances listed in Annex III. (Our emphasis)<br />

The substances listed in Annex III are:<br />

• Polychlorinated dibenzo-p-dioxins and dibenz<strong>of</strong>urans (PCDD/PCDF)<br />

• Hexachlorobenzene (HCB) (CAS No: 118-74-1)<br />

• Polychlorinated biphenyls (PCB)<br />

• Polycyclic aromatic hydrocarbons (PAHs)<br />

The incineration <strong>of</strong> waste clearly results in releases <strong>of</strong> all these substances -<br />

especially within residues, but also in emissions to atmosphere. 1089 It follows directly<br />

from this that the EPA, in considering any proposals for incinerators is required to:<br />

“give priority consideration to alternative processes, techniques or practices<br />

that have similar usefulness” but which avoid the formation and release <strong>of</strong><br />

PCDD/PCDF, HCB, PCB and PAHs.<br />

The same applies to other processes which are net emitters <strong>of</strong> these compounds.<br />

A document produced by the Stockholm Convention, Guidelines On Best Available<br />

Techniques And Provisional Guidance On Best Environmental Practices, provides an<br />

outline <strong>of</strong> the approach that is envisaged to be necessary to satisfy the<br />

requirement. 1090 The guidelines suggest, for example, that this assessment may be<br />

undertaken which includes, for example:<br />

“a comparison <strong>of</strong> the proposed process, the available alternatives and the<br />

applicable legislation using what might be termed a “checklist approach”,<br />

keeping in mind the overall sustainable development context and taking fully<br />

into account environmental, health, safety and socio-economic factors.”<br />

The meaning <strong>of</strong> “priority consideration” in the context <strong>of</strong> the development <strong>of</strong><br />

incineration capacity, or <strong>of</strong> the capacity for other waste treatment facilities, within<br />

Ireland is not entirely clear. How such consideration should be given is perhaps a<br />

moot point. On the one hand, the provisional low POPs threshold under the Stockholm<br />

Convention is not an especially low threshold by EU standards. On the other hand, the<br />

spirit <strong>of</strong> the Convention would appear to imply something rather more stringent, and it<br />

1089 See, for example, European Commission (2006) Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control<br />

Reference Document on the Best Available Techniques for <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration, 2006.<br />

1090 Stockholm Convention (2007) Guidelines On Best Available Techniques And Provisional Guidance<br />

On Best Environmental Practices Relevant To Article 5 And Annex C Of The Stockholm Convention On<br />

Persistent Organic Pollutants - Adopted at COP 3, May 2007. 2007: Geneva, Switzerland.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


might be argued that no threshold applies, and the issue is whether or not a process<br />

is, on assessment, established to be a net emitter <strong>of</strong> dioxins and furans. The effects<br />

would most likely be quite significant for Ireland in terms <strong>of</strong> both recycling, and the<br />

consideration <strong>of</strong> alternatives to incineration. This matter has been discussed in more<br />

detail within a Strategic Environmental Assessment <strong>of</strong> a proposed Section 60 <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Direction. 1091<br />

As discussed in Annex 1.0, the UNECE POPs Protocol obliges Parties to reduce their<br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> dioxins, furans, polycyclic aromatic hydrocarbons (PAHs) and HCB below<br />

their levels in 1990 (or an alternative year between 1985 and 1995). The dioxin<br />

emissions in Ireland are low – and this is reflected in the most recent results <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ongoing national dioxin surveys. 1092 The 2002 dioxin inventory, however, suggests<br />

that Ireland plans to increase dioxin emissions over the period from 2000 to 2010<br />

and that the main increase would be in incinerator residues. 1093 It is difficult to<br />

reconcile this with the obligations <strong>of</strong> the UNECE POPs protocol.<br />

The addition <strong>of</strong> nine new POPs to the Convention at the fourth Conference <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Parties seems likely, within Europe, to lead to a revision <strong>of</strong> Regulation 850/2004, and<br />

this will have knock-on implications for Ireland. In this context, it would seem to make<br />

sense to avoid making commitments that prejudice future compliance with what is a<br />

predictable change in regulation. The Annex A listings <strong>of</strong> c-Octa BDE and c-Penta BDE<br />

significantly increase the likelihood that brominated dioxins and furans (‘PBDD/DFs’)<br />

will soon be proposed for similar listing because PBDD/DFs are both contaminants <strong>of</strong><br />

the newly listed flame retardants and are also by products from their combustion. It<br />

is notable that the EPA has already started testing for these compounds in the annual<br />

dioxin surveys. 1094<br />

Releases <strong>of</strong> unintentionally produced by-products (chlorinated dioxins, chlorinated<br />

furans, PCBs and HCB) are subject to continuous minimisation and ultimate<br />

elimination where feasible. The main tool for this is an action plan which should<br />

cover source inventories and release estimates, as well as plans for release<br />

reductions.<br />

The EPA is currently working on the preparation <strong>of</strong> a draft national implementation<br />

plan (NIP). 1095 Once completed this draft will be made available for public<br />

consultation. In June 2008 the EPA prepared a short consultation paper to provide<br />

interested parties with more information on the proposed NIP. Written<br />

1091 Eunomia (2009) Section 60 <strong>Policy</strong> Direction Capping Incineration <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> and Other<br />

Matters, Environmental Report for DoEHLG, June 2009.<br />

1092 C. Concannon (2008) Dioxin Levels in the Irish Environment 2007 Fifth Assessment Based on<br />

Levels in Cow's Milk November 2008. 2008: Dublin, Ireland<br />

1093 F. Hayes and I. Marnane (2002) Inventory <strong>of</strong> Dioxin and Furan emissions to air, land and water in<br />

Ireland for 2000 and 2010 Final Report, Prepared for the Environmental Protection Agency By URS<br />

Dames & Moore: Dublin.<br />

1094 C. Concannon (2008) Dioxin Levels in the Irish Environment 2007 Fifth Assessment Based on<br />

Levels in Cow's Milk November, Environmental Protection Agency, Ireland.<br />

1095 http://www.epa.ie/whatwedo/resource/hazardous/pops/<br />

864<br />

29/09/09


epresentations in relation to this consultation paper were invited up to 28th <strong>of</strong> July<br />

2008. The European Union completed and published an Implementation Plan in<br />

2007. 1096<br />

58.1 Recommendations<br />

Evidently, there is a need to progress the National Implementation Plan with some<br />

urgency. This plan will, presumably, have to consider the best approach to the<br />

Conventions in the light <strong>of</strong> their requirements.<br />

It is useful to define the main sources that give rise to POPs in the environment in<br />

order to consider where measures can be taken to reduce their generation or<br />

emission to the environment:<br />

865<br />

A) Pesticides (e.g. DDT);<br />

B) Industrial chemicals (e.g. polychlorinated biphenyls (PCBs));<br />

C) Unintentional by-products (e.g. dioxins, furans).<br />

In relation to POPs arising from Source A), although regulation on the production and<br />

use <strong>of</strong> pesticides is clearly a valuable measure (and the EPA is naturally the<br />

appropriate responsible authority to administer this), this may be considered outside<br />

the scope <strong>of</strong> this review <strong>of</strong> waste policy.<br />

The requirements <strong>of</strong> the UNECE / Stockholm Conventions imply, in relation to Source<br />

B), regulation on the use <strong>of</strong> industrial chemicals which utilise or have potential to give<br />

rise to POPs. In this regard, many <strong>of</strong> the policy measures explored in other sections <strong>of</strong><br />

this annex have significant relevance. The obligation for producer responsibility,<br />

minimum recycling standards, and levies and bans on specific substances are<br />

measures which can reduce or eliminate the risk <strong>of</strong> environmental accumulation <strong>of</strong><br />

POPs.<br />

In relation to Source C), there is clear benefit to be derived from minimising the<br />

generation and dispersion <strong>of</strong> POPs as unintended by-products <strong>of</strong> waste treatment<br />

processes. Two potentially complimentary policy developments present themselves<br />

here:<br />

1. To ensure that any technologies used for the treatment <strong>of</strong> waste which may<br />

give rise to POPs operate to high environmental standards; and<br />

2. In the light <strong>of</strong> the possible alternatives available, to seek to reduce the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> material that passes to technologies that might give rise to<br />

additional emissions <strong>of</strong> POPs in order to reduce their generation and<br />

dispersal.<br />

In relation to the first point, some more detailed policy assessment has been carried<br />

out for the DoEHLG. The proposed Section 60 policy direction seeks to achieve a<br />

1096 Commision <strong>of</strong> the European Communities (2007) Community Implementation Plan for the<br />

Stockholm Convention on Persistent Organic Pollutants Commision Staff Working Document<br />

SEC(2007) 341, 9.3.2007.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


number <strong>of</strong> objectives, the last <strong>of</strong> these specifically relevant to the issue <strong>of</strong> POPs and<br />

their generation from (thermal) waste treatment: 1097<br />

866<br />

29/09/09<br />

“to reduce air soil and water pollution from incineration and comply with the<br />

Stockholm Convention”<br />

The second point here implies that waste minimisation, and diversion <strong>of</strong> material up<br />

the waste hierarchy (or to non-thermal waste treatment technologies) should be<br />

encouraged in the first instance, thereby reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> material which may<br />

give rise to POPs from thermal treatment. There are some issues here in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

some <strong>of</strong> the recycling processes themselves (at least where, for example, flame<br />

retardants are concerned).<br />

Where recycling is not possible, the aim should design out substances <strong>of</strong> concern,<br />

through, for example, producer responsibility measures, or more generally,<br />

implementing substance bans.<br />

In respect <strong>of</strong> treatment, the issue <strong>of</strong> “priority consideration to alternative processes,<br />

techniques or practices that have similar usefulness but which avoid the formation<br />

and release <strong>of</strong> PCDD/PCDF, HCB, PCB and PAHs” remains <strong>of</strong> significance. It would<br />

appear to be <strong>of</strong> some relevance to ensure that guidance is produced detailing how<br />

the requirement to give ‘priority consideration’ is to be implemented.<br />

The full scope <strong>of</strong> the measures to tackle POPs need to be addressed within the<br />

National Implementation Plan. In addition to the currently legislated requirements, a<br />

forward looking plan will need to consider the new POPs added at the most recent<br />

Conference <strong>of</strong> the Parties. It is notable that the EPA has demonstrated its ability to<br />

take such a forward look in respect <strong>of</strong> monitoring.<br />

1097 Eunomia (2009) Section 60 <strong>Policy</strong> Direction Capping Incineration <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> and Other<br />

Matters, Environmental Report for DoEHLG, June 2009.


TARGET SETTING<br />

867<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


59.0 Target Setting<br />

Discussions regarding targets <strong>of</strong>ten focus upon whether objectives can be deemed to<br />

be ‘SMART’. The term ‘SMART’ is an acronym that is interpreted in various ways.<br />

However, we interpret it as follows:<br />

1) The degree to which the targets can be said to be well defined for the meeting <strong>of</strong><br />

the desired objectives (are they Specific?);<br />

2) Whether or not the targets are measurable (are they Measurable?); and<br />

3) The degree to which one might state that they are appropriately set (are they<br />

Achievable, and are they Timed? 1098).<br />

4) The degree to which the targets could be said to lead to the desired outcomes,<br />

whether in a direct sense, or indirectly through changing behaviour (their<br />

Relevance).<br />

In addition, <strong>of</strong> considerable relevance are the following:<br />

5) What the ‘desired outcomes’ actually are (which might be deemed linked to the<br />

test <strong>of</strong> specificity);<br />

6) The degree to which the targets are addressed to the right person (is there a<br />

defined Addressee for the target?); and<br />

7) The degree to which the objectives and targets could be said to have avoided the<br />

potential for perverse outcomes (Perversity avoidance);<br />

We would suggest that targets should be appraised against these questions,<br />

effectively appraising whether they are ‘SMART’ targets with an additional ‘P’ for nonperversity,<br />

and an additional ‘A’ for the addressee. 1099 We have, for ease <strong>of</strong> reference,<br />

referred to the test as the TRAMPAS test.<br />

It should be said that not all targets necessarily need a well-defined addressee. It<br />

seems sensible to distinguish between targets against which performance is to be<br />

measured, and used to guide the development <strong>of</strong> policy, and those which effectively<br />

have to be met, being related to a legal or statutory requirement, or to a target which<br />

is seen as important for environmental reasons. In the case <strong>of</strong> the former, where<br />

performance against the target might be difficult to ‘devolve’ downwards, then<br />

configuring policy and incentives to enable the target to be met, and adjusting these<br />

policy tools where they appear unlikely to be met, becomes the key issue. In the case<br />

<strong>of</strong> the latter, it seems more necessary to assign responsibility for meeting targets to<br />

1098 If a target is not achievable, it will generally be because it is too challenging. Whether a target is<br />

challenging or not will informed by the timeframe given over to achieve the target.<br />

1099 Since discussion <strong>of</strong> SMART targets is <strong>of</strong>ten taking place within an organisation, it is <strong>of</strong>ten taken as<br />

read that they are<br />

868<br />

29/09/09


specific actors, or failing that, to take a very active role in reviewing policy to ensure<br />

the targets are met.<br />

59.1 Key Irish Targets<br />

The main Irish targets are set out below (see also Annex 6.0). Some, though by no<br />

means all, <strong>of</strong> these targets are set as a direct consequence <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> EU<br />

Directives. We highlight, alongside each, the issues with the targets as they were<br />

framed:<br />

From Changing Our Ways:<br />

869<br />

� Diverting 50% <strong>of</strong> household waste away from landfill by 2013;<br />

No clear addressee; no sanction for non-compliance; and limited policy drivers<br />

until very recently;<br />

� A minimum 65% reduction in biodegradable wastes consigned to landfill by<br />

2013;<br />

No addressee(s); no sanction for non-compliance; limited policy drivers until<br />

very recently; relevance not clear when set alongside other targets (for<br />

example, even if waste had not grown, the suggestion is that recycling would<br />

account for a relatively small fraction <strong>of</strong> the reduction);<br />

� The development <strong>of</strong> waste recovery facilities employing environmentally<br />

beneficial technologies, as an alternative to landfill, including the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> composting and other feasible biological treatment facilities<br />

capable <strong>of</strong> treating up to 300,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> biodegradable waste per annum<br />

by 2013;<br />

No addressee(s); no sanction for non-compliance; limited policy drivers (and<br />

arguably, the ABPR has acted to limit development here, until very recently);<br />

potential for perverse outcomes (the ‘up to 300,000 tonnes’ potentially<br />

constrains capacity – it is likely that a figure in excess <strong>of</strong> this will be required<br />

by 2013);<br />

� Recycling <strong>of</strong> 35% <strong>of</strong> municipal waste by 2013;<br />

No addressee(s); no sanction for non-compliance; limited policy drivers; too<br />

easily achievable;<br />

� Recycling at least 50% <strong>of</strong> C&D waste within a five year period (by 2003), with<br />

a progressive increase to at least 85% over fifteen years (by 2013);<br />

No addressee(s); no sanction for non-compliance; limited policy drivers;<br />

absence <strong>of</strong> interim measures;<br />

� Rationalisation <strong>of</strong> municipal waste landfills, with progressive and sustained<br />

reductions in numbers, leading to an integrated network <strong>of</strong> some 20 state-<strong>of</strong>the-art<br />

facilities incorporating energy recovery and high standards <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental protection;<br />

Implicitly, this is aimed at the EPA and planners. It is not obvious what the<br />

relevance <strong>of</strong> the figure <strong>of</strong> 20 is, but the figure is specified in an appropriately<br />

vague manner;<br />

� An 80% reduction in methane emissions from landfill, which will make a<br />

useful contribution to meeting Ireland's international obligations;<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


870<br />

29/09/09<br />

No addressee(s); no sanction for non-compliance; unclear how this is being<br />

measured (and measurement may be quite different to ‘estimation’ in this<br />

respect).<br />

National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy<br />

� Reductions in biodegradable waste (relative to trend in arisings), <strong>of</strong> 3% each<br />

year (2005 to 2007), 4% each year (2008 to 2010), 5% each year (2011 to<br />

2013), and 6% each year (2014 to 2016);<br />

No addressee(s); no sanctions; unclear whether this is achievable;<br />

� Targets for home composting at 20% <strong>of</strong> urban households and 55% <strong>of</strong> rural<br />

households – equivalent to some 35% <strong>of</strong> all households - by 2010;<br />

No addressee(s); no sanctions; unclear how this would be measured (and what<br />

the current level is);<br />

� Capture rate for paper and cardboard:<br />

• 45% for households and 61% for commerce in 2010, corresponding to<br />

55% <strong>of</strong> overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW;<br />

• 55% for households and 71% for commerce in 2013, corresponding to<br />

65% <strong>of</strong> overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW; and<br />

• 60% for households and 73% for commerce in 2016, corresponding to<br />

67% <strong>of</strong> overall paper / cardboard generation within BMW.<br />

No addressee(s); no sanctions for non-compliance; policy drivers unclear;<br />

� For organic waste, the targets were:<br />

• 40% coverage for households and 60% coverage for commerce in<br />

2010 at an estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 45% to 60% respectively,<br />

corresponding to 25% <strong>of</strong> overall organic waste generation within BMW;<br />

• 45% coverage for households and 70% coverage for commerce in<br />

2013 at an estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 50% to 65% respectively,<br />

corresponding to 33% <strong>of</strong> overall organic waste generation within BMW;<br />

and<br />

• 50% coverage for households and 70% coverage for commerce in<br />

2016 at an estimated average yield <strong>of</strong> 55% to 70% respectively,<br />

corresponding to 36% <strong>of</strong> overall organic waste generation within BMW.<br />

No addressee(s); no sanctions for non-compliance; policy drivers only now<br />

being shaped;<br />

In addition, there are now targets which Ireland has to meet under the producer<br />

responsibility Directives. These targets are set at the lowest rates permissible under<br />

EU legislation. Generally, producers are required to demonstrate that they are<br />

meeting the required targets, though not all addressees face such targets (notably<br />

the ‘producers’ who are not classified as major ones for the purpose <strong>of</strong> the producer<br />

responsibility scheme for packaging).<br />

A clear and persistent theme in the setting <strong>of</strong> targets in Ireland is that, with some<br />

exceptions, there are no clear addressees, and that where there are no addressees,


policy has not been sufficiently responsive to deliver the desired outcome with any<br />

certainty. The best example is the Landfill Directive targets, whilst those in the<br />

National Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy. It is almost always the case that targets have<br />

been set with the presumption that Regions would embed these within the Regional<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans. However, there is no meaningful monitoring <strong>of</strong> these<br />

Plans, and even where the Plans show no sign <strong>of</strong> meeting their own targets, there is<br />

no plan to apply any sanction in this respect. Even if the Regions were to be made<br />

‘responsible’ for delivering on targets, to what extent would it be reasonable to<br />

assume, for example, that they should be sanctioned for failure to meet the required<br />

capture rate for commercial biowaste? The 2010 targets in the National<br />

Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong> Strategy look, today, worryingly difficult to achieve, yet no one<br />

will ‘pay’, or face any other sanction, for failure in this regard because no one is<br />

obviously responsible for the targets.<br />

It seems clear that one lesson from this experience is that Ireland needs to change its<br />

‘hands-<strong>of</strong>f’ mentality where target setting is concerned, especially where these are<br />

ones which have to be met as a matter <strong>of</strong> (European) law. In addition, where it seeks<br />

to ensure that its own objectives are to be met, then where these are considered <strong>of</strong><br />

high relevance, these should be supported by policies which drive matters towards<br />

meeting the target, and devolution <strong>of</strong> targets to relevant addressees as appropriate,<br />

supported by sanctions for non-compliance. If no appropriate addressee exists, then<br />

policy should adjust to meeting targets. In cases where targets seem likely to met with<br />

ease, then consideration should be given to revising these to improve later<br />

performance.<br />

Ireland has to consider which targets to set, in the light <strong>of</strong> consideration <strong>of</strong> who<br />

should have (can reasonably take) responsibility for them, and how sanctions will be<br />

applied to ensure compliance. The role <strong>of</strong> Government should be to ensure that<br />

targets are set and, where appropriate, made the responsibility <strong>of</strong> those who can be<br />

made responsible for their delivery.<br />

Target setting does need take into account:<br />

871<br />

• data availability, and<br />

• availability <strong>of</strong> proxy information,<br />

In some cases, it may be appropriate to highlight the desirability <strong>of</strong> specific targets<br />

without setting them until more data and information is available. This is particularly<br />

important in respect <strong>of</strong>, for example, targets set relative to an ongoing trend. Until this<br />

trend is established, setting targets can lead to overly, or under-ambitious targets.<br />

59.2 Objectives for Targets<br />

The types <strong>of</strong> objectives which have been the focus <strong>of</strong> targets in other countries are:<br />

1. Reducing Reducing waste waste production production (household waste, municipal waste, business<br />

waste, public authority waste, commercial waste, industrial waste, hazardous<br />

waste, construction and demolition waste);<br />

These objectives find expression in terms <strong>of</strong>:<br />

a. Requirements to reduce growth in a waste stream relative to ‘business<br />

as usual’ trends (Flanders);<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


872<br />

29/09/09<br />

b. Requirements for pay-by-use <strong>of</strong> households (e.g. South Korea, Italy);<br />

c. Targets for residual waste per inhabitant (e.g. Wales, England,<br />

Flanders);<br />

2. Increasing Increasing re re-use re use use <strong>of</strong> selected streams (ELVs, household waste, municipal<br />

waste, construction and demolition waste);<br />

Other than in some countries, where targets for the proportion <strong>of</strong> beverage<br />

containers to be in refillables exist (e.g. Germany), we are not aware <strong>of</strong> specific<br />

targets for re-use in different countries since these are usually combined with<br />

recycling or recovery targets (as in the case <strong>of</strong> ELVs). Like waste prevention, reuse<br />

tends to be a ‘Cinderella area’ <strong>of</strong> waste policy despite its position in the<br />

hierarchy, the exception being deposit refunds (see Annex 16.0);<br />

3. Increasing Increasing recycling recycling <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> selected selected streams streams (packaging, ELVs, household waste,<br />

municipal waste, construction waste, construction and demolition waste):<br />

These are probably the most common targets and are used in many countries.<br />

However, the ease with which recycling targets can be met and the cost<br />

implications <strong>of</strong> doing so vary across actors in the economy. For producers <strong>of</strong><br />

large quantities <strong>of</strong> homogenous waste streams, such targets may present no<br />

financial or technical problem. Problems can relate to perverse incentives, as<br />

well as the definition <strong>of</strong> ‘recycling’. The definitional issues are especially<br />

important where construction and demolition wastes are concerned given that<br />

many Member States – including the UK – exempt from licensing some<br />

activities through which large tonnages <strong>of</strong> material are handled;<br />

4. Increasing Increasing Increasing recovery recovery <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> selected selected streams streams (packaging, ELVs, household waste,<br />

municipal waste, construction and demolition waste);<br />

These targets are also common. They need – at least ins<strong>of</strong>ar as specific waste<br />

streams are concerned – to pay particular attention to what modes <strong>of</strong> recovery<br />

are likely to be used. The hierarchy under Article 4 gives priority to materials<br />

recycling with other forms <strong>of</strong> recovery ranked lower. To the extent that recovery<br />

targets are set, they need to respect the extent <strong>of</strong> latitude which the term<br />

‘recovery’ may imply, so it is becoming more common in the EU for targets for<br />

recycling and for recovery to be set.<br />

5. Reducing Reducing residual residual waste waste quantities quantities (household waste);<br />

This objective has been deployed in Flanders and Walloonia in Belgium and is<br />

also one <strong>of</strong> three National Indicators for waste which English local authorities<br />

are expected to report. In Flanders and Walloonia, the target has generally<br />

supported the introduction <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use for waste. In England, the reporting <strong>of</strong><br />

the indicator is not such that any local authority faces any sanction if the<br />

national target (225kg/inh) is not met. There are also no interim targets. In<br />

Walloonia, a residual waste levy system was used to give authorities an<br />

incentive to keep below the national target (see below);<br />

6. Reducing Reducing the the the quantity quantity quantity <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> waste waste waste sent sent to to landfill landfill; landfill<br />

It is not clear how many Member States actually set targets to reduce<br />

quantities <strong>of</strong> waste sent to landfill, but given that many Member States deploy<br />

bans <strong>of</strong> narrower or broader scope, this objective is more or less implicit (see<br />

Annex 52.0). The different drivers are considered below. The justification for<br />

this target usually relates to reducing the landfilling <strong>of</strong> ‘resources’. However, a


873<br />

ban only ensures the best use <strong>of</strong> those resources where complementary<br />

measures ensure waste is moved up the hierarchy and to options where the<br />

environmental impact is superior. Our research indicates that success in this<br />

regard is, at best, mixed. The wording <strong>of</strong> some bans tends to imply that the<br />

objective is to ensure that waste which can be combusted to generate energy<br />

is used for that purpose. If sufficient measures are in place to promote<br />

recycling strategies, this might be acceptable. In many cases, however, this is<br />

clearly not the case;<br />

7. Limit Limiting Limit Limiting<br />

ing the the the quantity quantity quantity <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> waste waste waste sent sent sent for for for incineration incineration;<br />

incineration<br />

Whilst there appear to be no specific targets for this, again, there are some<br />

measures which imply a desire to ensure environmental standards are not<br />

compromised. <strong>Waste</strong> sorting in many municipalities in Japan distinguishes<br />

between ‘burnable’ and ‘non-burnable’ waste, with plastics being treated as<br />

‘non-burnable’ owing to problems with dioxins in the past. In Denmark, treated<br />

wood is banned from incineration, presumably owing to the potential for<br />

emission <strong>of</strong> furans and possibly brominated dioxins from its combustion. In<br />

Flanders, a ban on unsorted waste being sent to incineration is intended to<br />

ensure that the ban on landfilling does not lead to a simple switch from landfill<br />

to incineration. This reflects the fact that in Flanders, the aim is to promote<br />

prevention, re-use and recycling. In Denmark, on the other hand, the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

policy has been to shift waste away from landfill and into incineration. A brief<br />

comparison <strong>of</strong> recycling rates in Flanders and Denmark highlights the fact that<br />

as regards household type waste, Denmark’s recycling rate stood at 29% in<br />

2001, with the aim to increase this to 33% by 2008. 61% <strong>of</strong> waste was<br />

incinerated in 2001, and it was intended that this should be reduced to 60%<br />

by 2008. In Flanders, source separation rates now stand at 71%, a level which<br />

would be very difficult for Denmark to achieve given its existing infrastructure;<br />

and<br />

8. Reducing Reducing Reducing GHG GHG emissions from waste management<br />

management;<br />

management<br />

The England strategy includes an objective <strong>of</strong> this nature though no specific<br />

policy mechanism to deliver this. Rather than being an objective, this seems to<br />

be an assessment <strong>of</strong> the consequences <strong>of</strong> doing what the strategy seeks to<br />

achieve. There is a serious problem with setting this as an objective in the way<br />

that the English strategy has calculated it. The assessment is carried out ‘as if<br />

waste prevention does not matter’. The consequence is that because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

methodology and baseline used, then as growth rates increase, the claimed<br />

benefits increase under a given apportionment <strong>of</strong> waste across the different<br />

management routes. Caution would need to be used if this measure was<br />

deployed, and one might argue that it should only be used once the energy<br />

used in manufacturing materials in the first place enters into the equation.<br />

Finally, there are objectives which relate to the waste sector but in an indirect<br />

manner, and where key drivers might relate to sectors other than waste per se. These<br />

might relate to, for example, the application <strong>of</strong> waste-derived organic matter on land,<br />

or the generation <strong>of</strong> renewable energy from waste, and the related drivers might be<br />

found in other sectoral strategies.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


59.3 Looking Forward<br />

In order to be aligned with the <strong>Waste</strong> Framework Directive (see Annex 1.0), and to<br />

pre-empt 2014 revisions, a forward looking approach would (with regard to targets):<br />

874<br />

1. Develop Develop objectives objectives in in line line with with the the hierarchy hierarchy outlined in in in Article Article 4 4 <strong>of</strong> the WFD;<br />

2. Include a specific programme for waste prevention prevention. prevention<br />

A forward looking strategy<br />

would pre-empt the decoupling objective foreseen by the WFD;<br />

3. Put Put in in place place means means to to ensure ensure that that targets targets for for recycling recycling <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> at at least least 50% 50% from<br />

from<br />

household household waste waste and and 70% 70% from from constructi construction constructi on and demolition waste waste are are met met in<br />

the spirit <strong>of</strong> pre-empting the WFD objectives;<br />

4. Ensure Ensure that that mechanisms mechanisms are are in in place place which which lead lead to to the the separate separate collection collection <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

glass, glass, glass, metals, metals, metals, paper paper paper and and and plastic plastic plastic (where (where (where appropriate),<br />

appropriate), appropriate), again pre-empting the<br />

WFD requirements. This requirement relates to materials rather than specific<br />

waste streams, and does not apply to household / municipal waste waste only only; only<br />

5. Implement mplement mplement measures measures designed designed to to lead lead to to separate separate collection collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> biowaste, biowaste, but but<br />

this this this should should should be be be extended extended extended beyond beyond beyond the the the municipal municipal municipal waste waste waste str stream str stream<br />

eam; eam<br />

6. Implement policies policies or or mechanisms mechanisms that that encourage the use use <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> products products <strong>of</strong><br />

biowaste biowaste management<br />

management;<br />

management<br />

management<br />

7. Include a vision vision which which might might include the concept <strong>of</strong> resource resource efficiency efficiency. efficiency<br />

These would appear to be more or less essential components <strong>of</strong> policy for Ireland if it<br />

is intended that this review should be relatively robust over time. Indeed, one might<br />

argue that genuinely progressive policy would go some way beyond these measures<br />

and targets since they may yet become the minimum requirements for policy which<br />

seeks to defend itself from the need for constant updating.<br />

The types <strong>of</strong> target which should set are likely to be:<br />

� Reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> household waste generated relative to an existing<br />

trend;<br />

� Reducing the quantity <strong>of</strong> other wastes generated against existing trends.<br />

These targets should be set with a view to linking to output measures (in other<br />

words, they should seek to embody some measure <strong>of</strong> the efficiency <strong>of</strong><br />

resource us – if they do not reflect output measures, then declining use can<br />

simply reflect changing economic structures). If these targets cannot be set,<br />

because <strong>of</strong> data limitations, then they should not be included at this juncture;<br />

� Targets which promote recycling <strong>of</strong> household wastes;<br />

� Targets for recycling <strong>of</strong> commercial and industrial wastes;<br />

� Targets for recycling construction and demolition wastes;<br />

� Targets related to the phasing out <strong>of</strong> landfilling <strong>of</strong> specific waste streams /<br />

waste which has not been pre-treated. This component is already in<br />

development through the EPA.<br />

In the medium term, it may be appropriate for Ireland to set climate change-related<br />

targets. Several countries already seek to measure climate change impacts, and<br />

29/09/09


ecent reports from PROGNOS, the EEA and Defra / Committee on Climate Change /<br />

the Environment Agency, as well as the waste strategies <strong>of</strong> England and Wales,<br />

indicate that interest in this area is growing. 1100 However, a key issue with target<br />

setting in this area is that because some management methods, for example,<br />

recycling, are assigned (in most studies) negative contributions to the climate change<br />

indicator, the perverse consequence can arise that improvements relative to a<br />

baseline are greater the greater is the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste in the waste stream. Hence,<br />

absolute indicators are required, which seek reductions from a fixed level.<br />

Key policy measures are likely to be:<br />

875<br />

1. The extension <strong>of</strong> producer responsibility to a wider range <strong>of</strong> materials;<br />

2. Lifting targets for recycling under producer responsibility;<br />

3. Strengthening <strong>of</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> re-use measures in existing and future<br />

producer responsibility schemes;<br />

4. Minimum requirements for source separation schemes for:<br />

a. Households;<br />

b. Commerce and industry;<br />

5. Minimum requirements, in terms <strong>of</strong> sorting, in the case <strong>of</strong> construction and<br />

demolition waste;<br />

6. The mandatory use – once collection schemes are <strong>of</strong> sufficient quality - <strong>of</strong> payby-use<br />

for households and / or measures to encourage this (such as a residual<br />

waste levy);<br />

7. A pre-treatment requirement for landfilling to be phased in over time;<br />

8. A ban on specific materials being landfilled or incinerated;<br />

Other measures which might support the approach, but which, arguably, belong in<br />

other sectors might include agri-environmental measures to encourage the use <strong>of</strong><br />

compost and digestate in agriculture (subject to specific standards being met). These<br />

might mimic payments made in some Italian regions to farmers in lieu <strong>of</strong> the<br />

improvement in the organic matter status <strong>of</strong> soils which this represents. 1101<br />

1100 The USEPA encourages local authorities to use its WARM model to calculate greenhyouse gas<br />

reduction benefits from recycling. See also, for example, G. Dehoust et al, Status Report on the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Sector’s Contribution to Climate Protection and Possible Potentials, Federal Ministry for the<br />

Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety, August 2005; ERM (2006) Carbon Balances<br />

and Energy Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> UK <strong>Waste</strong>s, Final Report for Defra, December 2006;<br />

Eunomia (2009) Development <strong>of</strong> Marginal Abatement Cost Curves for the <strong>Waste</strong> Sector, Report for the<br />

Committee on Climate Change, Defra and the Environment Agency; M. Skovgaard, N. Hedal and A.<br />

Villanueva, F. Andersen and H. Larsen (2008) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Greenhouse Gases,<br />

ETC/RWM Working Paper 2008/1, January 2008; Prognos, with Infu and Ifeu (2008) Resource<br />

Savings and CO2 Reduction Potential in <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in Europe and the Possible Contribution<br />

to the CO2 Reduction Target in 2020, Berlin: October 2008.<br />

1101 See Enzo Favoino and Dominic Hogg (2008) The Potential Role <strong>of</strong> Compost in Reducing<br />

Greenhouse Gases, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Research, 2008; pp. 26; 61.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


59.4 Levels <strong>of</strong> Achievement – Household / Municipal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

The level at which targets might be set might be influenced by whether they are to be<br />

made statutory or not:<br />

876<br />

1. Where targets are to be made statutory, what is deemed to be possible, with<br />

the emphasis placed upon being suitably ambitious. As far as possible, the<br />

target should be deemed likely to lead to beneficial outcomes;<br />

2. Where targets are to be non statutory, or where they are not backed by<br />

sanctions, there is reason to believe that they can be set at more ambitious<br />

levels, seeking to push boundaries. It is possible that such targets might not<br />

be met. The aim, however, should be to orient policies in order to meet such<br />

targets.<br />

Of course, the latter type <strong>of</strong> target risks being seen as ‘tokenism’, whilst the tendency<br />

with any target tends to be – perhaps for political reasons – to ensure that they can<br />

be met, sometimes, rather easily.<br />

One jurisdiction which has not been afraid to establish challenging targets is the<br />

Flemish region <strong>of</strong> Belgium. The Flemish Government’s household waste plan 1997-<br />

2001 set the following objectives (using 1995 as a baseline – see Table 59-1):<br />

• <strong>Waste</strong> reduction targets <strong>of</strong> 6 per cent by 2001 and <strong>of</strong> 10 per cent by 2006,<br />

later revised to 13% by 2007 (measured relative to trend);<br />

• Recycling rates <strong>of</strong> 52 per cent by 2001 and 55 per cent by 2006, rising to 70%<br />

thereafter; and<br />

• Each municipality was set the target <strong>of</strong> generating less than 150<br />

kg/inhabitant/year <strong>of</strong> residual waste by 2006.<br />

Earlier in the decade, eight <strong>of</strong> the 20 incinerators in existence in 1991 had been<br />

closed despite bans on landfilling in place since 1998 (see below).<br />

Table 59-1: Targets for Flemish Household <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Year Year <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> prevention prevention prevention <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> recycling recycling +<br />

+<br />

composting<br />

composting<br />

29/09/09<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> incineration incineration +<br />

+<br />

landfill<br />

landfill<br />

1995 0 % 34 % 66 %<br />

2001 6 % 52 % 48 %<br />

2006 10 % 55 % 45 %<br />

Source: OVAM<br />

In support <strong>of</strong> the recycling objectives, minimum requirements were established in law<br />

for waste collection by the municipalities in the Flemish region (by waste stream).<br />

They were:<br />

� Requirements to collect waste door-to-door, applicable for residual waste,<br />

bulky waste, organic waste, paper and cardboard, packaging waste;<br />

� Requirements for locating bottle banks and textile containers at a density <strong>of</strong><br />

1/1000 inhabitants or more (otherwise, the use <strong>of</strong> door-to-door collection);


877<br />

� Separate collection at the containerpark, covering 20 - 40 different types <strong>of</strong><br />

waste; and<br />

� Special collection systems for city centres, rural municipalities, tourist/coastal<br />

areas.<br />

For door to door collections, it should be added that minimum frequencies were<br />

established.<br />

In Flanders today, virtually all municipalities make use <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use systems. The<br />

evolution <strong>of</strong> charges for sacks, and typical charges for schemes combining weight and<br />

volume based schemes with a charge per pick up are shown in Table 59-2 and Table<br />

59-3. Using these charges, the average costs <strong>of</strong> waste management for households in<br />

Flanders have been calculated as € 225 per household (2.4 persons). This is<br />

composed <strong>of</strong>;<br />

1. € 30 paid through the producers responsibility<br />

2. € 195 paid at municipality, broken down broadly as follows:<br />

a. 1/3 taxes related to the amount <strong>of</strong> waste (variable cost)<br />

b. 1/3 fixed household waste tax/household (fixed cost)<br />

c. 1/3 general taxes related to household income<br />

Table 59-2: Charges for 60l Sacks (€/sack)<br />

Year Year Year 1996 1996 1998 1998 1998 2000 2000 2003 2003 2007 2007 Maximum<br />

Maximum<br />

Euro 0.44 0.60 0.66 1.14 1.25-1.50 2<br />

Table 59-3: Charges Used in Flanders for 120l Bins<br />

Charge Charge Base Base Base<br />

Charge Charge Rate<br />

Rate<br />

Volume Based Charge €2.5/litre<br />

Weight Based Charge €0.15-0.2/kg<br />

Frequency Based Charge (per pick-up) €0.5-1/pickup<br />

Charges are generally applied to the following items:<br />

� per volume or weight, fully or only for big quantities<br />

� organic waste (garden + kitchen)<br />

� bulky waste<br />

� wood<br />

� demolition waste<br />

� organic waste<br />

� nappies<br />

They are generally zero, or close to zero, for:<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


878<br />

� textiles<br />

� glass<br />

� paper and cardboard<br />

� old metals<br />

� small dangerous wastes<br />

� when producers responsibility<br />

� Light packaging fraction (only €0.125 for cost <strong>of</strong> production and distribution <strong>of</strong><br />

the blue bag).<br />

In Flanders, this approach has delivered considerable success. The residual waste<br />

target has largely been met, whilst recycling rates are <strong>of</strong> the order 70%.<br />

The Flemish approach is interesting. The targets for residual waste effectively<br />

encourage both recycling and composting / digestion as well as waste prevention.<br />

Recycling targets do not do this. Indeed, in some countries, recycling targets can be<br />

met through collecting additional quantities <strong>of</strong> waste, notably garden waste, with<br />

relatively limited impact on the quantity <strong>of</strong> residual waste generated. A residual waste<br />

target is, in short, better aligned with the hierarchy that a straightforward recycling<br />

target.<br />

It could be argued that a waste prevention target and a waste recycling target, acting<br />

together, could achieve similar, perhaps better, results. However, prevention targets<br />

are not straightforward to set (especially where data is not <strong>of</strong> high quality), and<br />

indeed, the targets might need to be differentiated across local authorities depending<br />

upon current performance. Residual waste targets are, to some degree, fairer across<br />

local authority types. Some inhabitants, residing in flats, generate less waste than<br />

those in rural areas, especially in respect <strong>of</strong> garden waste. Where garden waste is<br />

collected, authorities may collect more waste, but high recycling rates can be<br />

achieved relatively straightforwardly.<br />

It is important to stress that the question as to what levels <strong>of</strong> performance can be<br />

achieved in future, and what that might imply for maximum levels <strong>of</strong> performance, is<br />

not the same as the question ‘what level <strong>of</strong> performance can be achieve today?’ or<br />

even, ‘what level <strong>of</strong> performance could be achieved today?’ It is a future-oriented<br />

question, and one whose answer will be affected by policy, as well as by wider<br />

developments in the nature <strong>of</strong> products, consumption and waste.<br />

There is no fixed maximum rate for recycling and composting / digestion <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

streams (for Ireland or anywhere else), and nor is there any clear understanding as to<br />

what might be achieved in respect <strong>of</strong> constraining waste growth, or reducing waste.<br />

The composition <strong>of</strong> waste streams, and the processes available for recycling them,<br />

will change over time, and are, at the margin, amenable to being shifted by policy.<br />

Technologies also change, allowing for new uses <strong>of</strong> materials collected separately<br />

from the waste stream. A brief review <strong>of</strong> recent history would demonstrate that in<br />

developed economies, where the challenges <strong>of</strong> recycling are arguably growing as the<br />

waste stream becomes more complex, the highest recycling rates being achieved are<br />

trending upwards over time, not down. Today, it is not uncommon for municipal waste<br />

recycling rates <strong>of</strong> 70% to be achieved in some regions, though no Member State<br />

29/09/09


achieves this rate country wide. Some regions where this rate is achieved do,<br />

however, cover a larger population than Ireland.<br />

At the same time, even before the economic crisis started to affect household<br />

consumption, there appeared to be evidence <strong>of</strong> some ‘de-linking’ <strong>of</strong> waste from<br />

economic growth. Countries where evidence <strong>of</strong> this was observed include England,<br />

Belgium (Flanders), Germany, Denmark and probably others besides. As such, as<br />

recycling rates have increase, and as waste growth has slowed, so the potential for<br />

targeting a declining quantity <strong>of</strong> residual waste has suggested itself.<br />

In Italy, the source separation <strong>of</strong> food waste has become a cornerstone for the<br />

achievement <strong>of</strong> very high recycling rates in some areas. In the Consorzia Priula, a<br />

consortium <strong>of</strong> municipalities near Treviso, the recycling rate for the area was 78% in<br />

2007. The figures for each municipality are shown in Figure 59-1. Figures for those<br />

municipalities included within the Consortium are shown in Figure 59-2, which shows<br />

how quickly the residual waste quantities dropped once a quality source separation<br />

scheme was put in place alongside pay-by-use charges. Indeed, residual waste<br />

quantities fell to less than 100kg per inhabitant per year.<br />

Figure 59-1: Recycling Rates in Priula, 2000 and 2007<br />

Source: Consorzio Priula<br />

879<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 59-2: Effects <strong>of</strong> Charging Scheme in Priula<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> (kg/inh/yr)<br />

880<br />

500<br />

450<br />

400<br />

350<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007<br />

Source: Consorzio Priula<br />

New Recycling<br />

Scheme Charging Scheme<br />

Introduced<br />

Year<br />

Recycling (kg/ing/yr)<br />

Residual (kg/inh/yr)<br />

Similar recycling rates can be observed in the area around Udine, in Italy, where food<br />

waste collections were introduced in 2008. Recycling rates in the area were<br />

averaging just under 80% in 2008 (see Figure 59-3). These examples are interesting<br />

precisely because they are recent examples from a nation which has not been widely<br />

viewed as a ‘high recycling nation’. They indicate that through novel adaptations <strong>of</strong><br />

existing ideas, notably the intensively targeted collection <strong>of</strong> food waste, very high<br />

recycling rates can be achieved when such systems are implemented alongside pay<br />

by use.<br />

Rates can be similarly high in other countries. The County <strong>of</strong> Schweinfurt in Germany<br />

achieves high recycling rates again through a combination <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use, and<br />

collection systems which are convenient and <strong>of</strong> broad scope. Figure 59-4 shows how,<br />

following the revision <strong>of</strong> the pay-by-use scheme in 1998/99, the recycling rate<br />

increased significantly to 76%, with residual waste falling to 92 kg per inhabitant.


Figure 59-3: Recycling Rates Around Udine<br />

Recycling Rate (%)<br />

881<br />

100%<br />

90%<br />

80%<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

0%<br />

Buttrio<br />

Camino al T.<br />

Mortegliano<br />

Nimis<br />

Pavia di Udine<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Pradamano<br />

Reana del Rojale<br />

Remanzacco<br />

Sedegliano<br />

Figure 59-4: Effects <strong>of</strong> Charging Scheme in Landkreis Schweinfurt<br />

Tonnes <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Collected<br />

70,000<br />

60,000<br />

50,000<br />

40,000<br />

30,000<br />

20,000<br />

10,000<br />

0<br />

Varmo<br />

AVERAGE<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Source: Hogg, D. (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges<br />

ENV/EPOC/WGWPR(2005)10/FINAL, Paris: OECD<br />

Year<br />

Recycling Rates<br />

Achieved<br />

Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Separately Collected


Some general observations are as follows:<br />

882<br />

� The highest recycling rates for household waste achieved over an area <strong>of</strong> a<br />

given size (in terms <strong>of</strong> household numbers) tends to decline as the number <strong>of</strong><br />

households covered increases (so in the best Italian regions, recycling rates<br />

are moving towards 60%, whilst at the local level, they may exceed 70%,<br />

though at the national level, rates are now around 50%). This is because<br />

recycling rates are calculated as averages. The larger the number <strong>of</strong><br />

households covered, the lower the maximum rate for the area <strong>of</strong> that size<br />

becomes. This is not necessarily due to ‘limits’. It may equally relate to the<br />

(limited) extent <strong>of</strong> diffusion <strong>of</strong> high performance systems across a region;<br />

� Even so, household recycling rates <strong>of</strong> 70% are achieved in regions with a<br />

greater number <strong>of</strong> households than are present in the whole <strong>of</strong> Ireland. For<br />

example, Flanders, a region <strong>of</strong> 6 million inhabitants in 308 municipalities<br />

(grouped in 25 intermunicipal waste management associations) achieved a<br />

rate for separate collection <strong>of</strong> 71% in 2005. 1102<br />

� The rates <strong>of</strong> recycling <strong>of</strong> municipal waste for the leading EU Member States –<br />

these are Austria, Germany, Belgium, Netherlands and Italy – are, according to<br />

most recent data, recycling 64%, 62%, 60%, 50% and 60%, respectively, <strong>of</strong><br />

municipal waste according to preliminary figures produced from Eurostat data<br />

for 2007. The figures for Austria, Germany and Belgium are country estimates,<br />

with the figures for 2006 suggesting rates <strong>of</strong> 67%, 62% and 58%<br />

respectively; 1103<br />

� Recycling rates tend to be highest in rural and suburban areas. In this respect,<br />

one could argue that Ireland ought to be capable <strong>of</strong> achieving higher, not<br />

lower, rates <strong>of</strong> recycling, though in practice, much depends upon how the<br />

matter is approached. In some rural regions <strong>of</strong> Austria, such as Upper Austria,<br />

the collection <strong>of</strong> recyclables is not so heavily focused on collection from the<br />

kerbside / doorstep, yet the recycling rate still reaches 70% (see Box 2). This<br />

experience highlights how adapting the collection <strong>of</strong> materials to specific<br />

circumstances can enable the achievement <strong>of</strong> high recycling rates in rural<br />

areas in an efficient manner. Other regions <strong>of</strong> Austria achieve high recycling<br />

rates in areas <strong>of</strong> relatively low population density.<br />

This brief review is at least suggestive <strong>of</strong> what might be achieved in future. If recycling<br />

rates <strong>of</strong> 70% or so are becoming more common locally, and if the trend is upwards, it<br />

would seem to make sense to consider targeting those sorts <strong>of</strong> rates in a country<br />

where the waste management system is ‘in development’ at some stage in the future.<br />

Similarly, if Ireland is to constrain household waste generation, residual waste targets<br />

should reflect such rates in the context <strong>of</strong> relatively static waste arisings.<br />

1102 OVAM (u.d.) Activiteitenoverzicht 2006, Mechelen: OVAM.<br />

1103 This data has been gathered<br />

29/09/09


Box 2: Recycling Centres in Upper Austria<br />

The company LAVU AG operates a system <strong>of</strong> bring collection centres across Upper<br />

Austria. The Region is organised into 445 municipalities grouped into 18 provinces<br />

which are responsible for waste management in their area. The Region covers 1.4<br />

million inhabitants, living in 550,000 hhlds, across an area <strong>of</strong> 12,000 km 2.<br />

In 1990, more than 60% <strong>of</strong> waste was sent to landfill. Now, 30% <strong>of</strong> waste is sent for<br />

some form <strong>of</strong> disposal. This change has been based upon a system <strong>of</strong> bring banks<br />

and the introduction <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Centres (WCCs). 180 WCCs have been<br />

erected to collect up to 70 different waste materials, which can be recycled at a later<br />

date. These collection centers are public buildings, where residents are invited to<br />

bring their waste and separate it in different boxes and containers. Specially trained<br />

employees are present at all times to help and encourage this service.<br />

In rural parts <strong>of</strong> the country each WCC services approximately 10,000 inhabitants; in<br />

urban areas this increases up to 50,000 inhabitants per WCC. These WCC are also<br />

used for collecting hazardous waste from households.<br />

The WCCs feed their materials into one Central Logistics Centre. The vehicles sent<br />

from the centre are compartmentalized and are specifically arranged so as to collect<br />

all materials (in their relative proportions) from a given WCC. The centre genuinely<br />

puts ‘reverse logistics’ into practice, dismantling WEEE items, making bi<strong>of</strong>uels from<br />

old vegetable oils, and recycling a bewildering range <strong>of</strong> different materials. 500 jobs<br />

have been created by the system.<br />

Preparing Vegetable Oil Containers Unloading a vehicle from the WCC<br />

for Unloading<br />

883<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The introduction <strong>of</strong> this waste system has resulted in an extremely high quality <strong>of</strong><br />

collected material and guarantees that 90% <strong>of</strong> all waste collected at WCCs is<br />

recycled. The overall performance <strong>of</strong> the waste management system is now such that<br />

71% <strong>of</strong> all waste is collected for recycling and composting. Collection fees for residual<br />

waste correlate roughly to population densities and are now between 80 and 220<br />

EURO per year for 13 pick ups <strong>of</strong> a 120 litre bin.<br />

884<br />

29/09/09<br />

Packaging for Recycling Other Dry Materials for Recycling<br />

Separately Collected Biowaste Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

WEEE Disassembly at the Central Logistics Centre


Source: Eunomia (2007) Scoping new Municipal waste Targets for Wales, Report to<br />

the WLGA, September 2007.<br />

59.5 Levels <strong>of</strong> Achievement for Packaging <strong>Waste</strong>s<br />

In reporting data on packaging recycling to the European Commission, Member<br />

States indicate packaging recycling rates as shown in Figure 59-5 to Figure 59-9, we<br />

show European recycling rates for packaging materials made from wood, glass, paper<br />

& board, metal and plastic, respectively.<br />

Ireland has the highest reported recycling rate for wood packaging at nearly 100%.<br />

Sweden, Denmark, Belgium and Luxembourg are all recovering very high percentages<br />

<strong>of</strong> glass, whilst Germany and Austria are not very far behind. The suggestion is that<br />

capture rates in excess <strong>of</strong> 90% for glass packaging should be achievable.<br />

Paper and board packaging has the highest overall recycling rate across Europe as<br />

shown in Figure 59-7. The packaging element <strong>of</strong> the paper and board stream may or<br />

may not be the best captured fraction. It might be supposed, however, that nonpackaging<br />

paper (such as newsprint and graphic papers from <strong>of</strong>fices and households)<br />

might be rather easier to capture at high rates than the packaging paper and card.<br />

The suggestion is that as with glass, paper and card could be captured at very high<br />

rates, in excess <strong>of</strong> 90%.<br />

Figure 59-5: Recycling Rates Achieved by Member States for Wood Packaging, 2006<br />

Figures<br />

Recycling Recycling Rate Rate (%)<br />

(%)<br />

885<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

A<br />

BE<br />

BU<br />

CY<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

CZ<br />

Source: EUROSTAT<br />

DK<br />

EST<br />

FI<br />

F<br />

GER<br />

GR<br />

H<br />

IRE<br />

IT<br />

LIT<br />

LUX<br />

M<br />

NO<br />

POL<br />

P<br />

ROM<br />

SLA<br />

SLO<br />

SP<br />

SWE<br />

UK<br />

Wood


Figure 59-6: Recycling Rates Achieved by Member States for Glass Packaging, 2006<br />

Figures<br />

Recycling Recycling Rate Rate (%)<br />

(%)<br />

886<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

29/09/09<br />

A<br />

BE<br />

BU<br />

CY<br />

CZ<br />

Source: EUROSTAT<br />

DK<br />

EST<br />

FI<br />

F<br />

GER<br />

GR<br />

H<br />

IRE<br />

Figure 59-7: Recycling Rates Achieved by Member States for Paper and Board<br />

Packaging, 2006 Figures<br />

Recycling Recycling Rate Rate (%)<br />

(%)<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

A<br />

BE<br />

BU<br />

CY<br />

Source: EUROSTAT<br />

CZ<br />

DK<br />

EST<br />

FI<br />

F<br />

GER<br />

GR<br />

H<br />

IRE<br />

IT<br />

IT<br />

LIT<br />

LIT<br />

LUX<br />

LUX<br />

M<br />

M<br />

NO<br />

NO<br />

POL<br />

POL<br />

P<br />

P<br />

ROM<br />

ROM<br />

SLA<br />

SLA<br />

SLO<br />

SLO<br />

SP<br />

SP<br />

SWE<br />

SWE<br />

UK<br />

UK<br />

Glass<br />

Paper & Board


Figure 59-8: Recycling Rates Achieved by Member States for Metal Packaging, 2006<br />

Figures<br />

Recycling Recycling Rate Rate (%)<br />

(%)<br />

887<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

A<br />

BE<br />

BU<br />

CY<br />

Source: EUROSTAT<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

CZ<br />

DK<br />

EST<br />

FI<br />

F<br />

GER<br />

GR<br />

H<br />

IRE<br />

IT<br />

Figure 59-9: Recycling Rates Achieved by Member States for Plastic Packaging, 2006<br />

Figures<br />

Recycling Recycling Rate Rate (%)<br />

(%)<br />

50<br />

45<br />

40<br />

35<br />

30<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

A<br />

BE<br />

BU<br />

CY<br />

CZ<br />

Source: EUROSTAT<br />

DK<br />

EST<br />

FI<br />

F<br />

GER<br />

GR<br />

H<br />

IRE<br />

IT<br />

LIT<br />

LIT<br />

LUX<br />

LUX<br />

M<br />

M<br />

NO<br />

NO<br />

POL<br />

POL<br />

P<br />

P<br />

ROM<br />

ROM<br />

SLA<br />

SLA<br />

SLO<br />

SLO<br />

SP<br />

SP<br />

SWE<br />

SWE<br />

UK<br />

UK<br />

Metals<br />

Plastic


Where metals are concerned, there is clearly room for improvement, but few Member<br />

States achieve, for metals, the sorts <strong>of</strong> recycling rate which they achieve for paper<br />

and board, or glass. This is somewhat surprising given a) the value <strong>of</strong> the material,<br />

and b) the ease with which it can be collected and sorted. Metal packaging materials<br />

might not be captured so well as larger, bulkier metal fractions, but at the same time,<br />

the relative quantities <strong>of</strong> metals in bulky items, and metal packaging within the Irish<br />

municipal stream may be relatively even. The data suggest that a capture rate <strong>of</strong> 80<br />

to 85% would be a challenging target.<br />

Where plastics are concerned, few Member States report a very high recycling rate.<br />

This is a consequence <strong>of</strong> the fact that whilst bottles might be well recycled, other<br />

materials, notably films, are not so well recycled. Indeed, some Member States take<br />

the view that non-bottle plastics are simply too expensive to target for recycling (a<br />

perspective which is assisted by the low targets for plastic packaging recycling under<br />

the Packaging Directive). Also, in some Green Dot schemes, only packaging marked<br />

with the Green Dot is actually collected through the collections set up through the<br />

system. Although the raw material has considerable value, plastics are more<br />

expensive to collect and can be costly to sort. This will be the most challenging<br />

material for which to achieve high recycling rates, particularly as one expands the<br />

range <strong>of</strong> materials beyond bottles.<br />

59.6 Levels <strong>of</strong> Achievement for Municipal Biowastes<br />

Where biowaste is concerned, the information on captures is less clear. However,<br />

there is considerable evidence to support the view that where garden waste is<br />

collected, the capture <strong>of</strong> garden waste tends to be extremely high. Flanders reports a<br />

capture rate <strong>of</strong> 94% for garden waste. 1104 In 1999, the Danish EPA reported that: ‘97<br />

per cent <strong>of</strong> garden waste was recycled in 1997... almost all garden waste is recycled<br />

today’. 1105 Note that the Danes also set a target for a maximum <strong>of</strong> 15% <strong>of</strong> garden<br />

waste to be incinerated in their 1993-7 Plan (which was clearly met). One <strong>of</strong> the<br />

reasons for high captures is that garden waste tends to draw additional waste into<br />

the waste stream. Consequently, the numerator and denominator, in calculating the<br />

recycling rate <strong>of</strong> the garden waste fraction, are similar, giving rise to high capture rate<br />

figures.<br />

Table 59-4 shows some countries with high performance in respect <strong>of</strong> biowaste<br />

collection. Most countries that have high capture rates for biowaste collect garden<br />

and kitchen waste together in their waste collections. This suggests that typically,<br />

captures <strong>of</strong> food waste achieved nationally are lower than those for garden waste.<br />

The approaches now being adopted in parts <strong>of</strong> Italy and Catalunya in Spain, however,<br />

target kitchen waste fractions in an attempt to optimise the collection system in terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> cost. Although these systems do not achieve the same level <strong>of</strong> biowaste capture (in<br />

1104 OVAM (2007) Evaluatierapportage 2006: Uitvoeringsplan Huishoudelijke Afvalst<strong>of</strong>fen 2003-2007,<br />

Mechelen: OVAM.<br />

1105 Danish EPA (1999) Environmental <strong>Review</strong> from the Danish EPA, No.1 1999, Copenhagen: Danish<br />

EPA.<br />

888<br />

29/09/09


absolute terms, i.e. in terms <strong>of</strong> weight per household), they prevent the ‘over-delivery’<br />

<strong>of</strong> garden waste into the waste stream when such material can be readily composted<br />

at home. Furthermore, they capture kitchen waste more accurately so the proportion<br />

<strong>of</strong> biowaste in the residual waste fraction tends to be lower.<br />

Table 59-4: Amount <strong>of</strong> Separately Collected and Composted Bio- and Green <strong>Waste</strong> in<br />

the EU<br />

Country Country Country Total Total Total MSW MSW MSW<br />

Organic Organic Organic MSW MSW<br />

MSW<br />

889<br />

excl excl excl home home<br />

home<br />

composting<br />

composting<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

incl incl incl home home<br />

home<br />

composting omposting<br />

omposting 1<br />

Separately<br />

Separately<br />

collected<br />

collected<br />

TOTAL<br />

TOTAL<br />

Separately Separately<br />

Separately<br />

collected collected<br />

collected<br />

as% as% total<br />

total<br />

Separately Separately<br />

Separately<br />

collected<br />

collected<br />

and and and home home<br />

home<br />

composted composted<br />

composted<br />

as% as% total<br />

total<br />

(inc (inc (inc home home<br />

home<br />

comp) comp)<br />

comp)<br />

Austria 2,800,000 800,000 1,570,000 600,000 75.00% 87.26%<br />

Flanders 3,126,044 1,158,795 1,264,795 723,795 62.46% 65.61%<br />

Denmark 2,780,000 973,000 652,000 67.01%<br />

Germany 49,100,000 9,000,000 7,000,000 77.78%<br />

Netherlands 8,220,000 3,452,400 1,790,000 51.85%<br />

Sources: Amlinger, F. (2000) ‘Composting in Europe: where do we go?’ Paper for the<br />

<strong>International</strong> Forum on Recycling, Madrid, 14 November 2000; Barth, J. (2000)<br />

‘Composting, quality assurance and compost utilisation - sustainable solutions in the<br />

European countries’, unpublished mimeograph; Hogg, D. et al. (2002) Economic<br />

Analysis <strong>of</strong> Options for Dealing with Biodegradable Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>, Final Report to<br />

the European Commission.<br />

1 In most <strong>of</strong> the European countries no statistical data about home-composting is<br />

available, so an estimation about full extent <strong>of</strong> the potential <strong>of</strong> organic waste is very<br />

difficult.<br />

As an example <strong>of</strong> the differentials between captures <strong>of</strong> food waste and captures <strong>of</strong><br />

garden waste, OVAM estimated that in 2005, capture rates for garden waste 94%,<br />

but captures for ‘GFT’ (non-meat kitchen waste) were 53%. It would seem reasonable<br />

to aim for very high captures <strong>of</strong> garden waste in Ireland. Ireland could achieve high<br />

captures <strong>of</strong> kitchen waste if the collection systems are well-designed. Captures <strong>of</strong> the<br />

order 60% would appear to be possible.<br />

59.7 Levels <strong>of</strong> Achievement for Non-household <strong>Waste</strong>s<br />

It is less common to find targets set for ‘commercial waste’ or ‘industrial waste’. Brief<br />

reflection suggests that this may be because the targets could not be made to<br />

meaningfully ‘stick’ on any specific addressee. The approach to improving<br />

performance in these areas focuses upon the use <strong>of</strong> one or more <strong>of</strong> the following:<br />

• Producer responsibility measures;


890<br />

• Mandates for the collection <strong>of</strong> specific waste fractions / streams;<br />

• Targets for pre-treatment facilities; and<br />

• Taxes and restrictions / bans on landfilling.<br />

In the commercial and industrial waste areas, the key differences are that for many<br />

industries, there is a strong link between the level <strong>of</strong> waste, and the company’s<br />

financial performance. As such, there is a strong motivation for waste prevention in<br />

many sectors. In addition, for many sectors, waste may be generated in relatively<br />

large and homogeneous quantities. The question regarding management is less one<br />

to do with which collection system to employ, and more one <strong>of</strong> the best destination for<br />

the collected material. For commercial enterprises, the nature <strong>of</strong> collection systems<br />

are more important, whilst the link between waste prevention and bottom line<br />

performance is weaker, though certainly not absent.<br />

Generally, as a consequence <strong>of</strong> these considerations, the potential for high levels <strong>of</strong><br />

‘landfill diversion’ (not necessarily ‘recycling’, as wastes might not always be suitable<br />

for recycling) in the industrial sector is significant. In the commercial sector, the<br />

potential to achieve high recycling rates ought to be greater than in the household<br />

sector, though somewhat similar owing to the nature <strong>of</strong> the wastes.<br />

OVAM’s activity report suggests that <strong>of</strong> industrial waste in Flanders, a significant<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> waste (63%) is sent initially to conditioning plants, with 16% recycled<br />

directly and 13% used as secondary materials. Ultimately, some 13% is incinerated<br />

and 12% landfilled, with the remainder effectively recycled, or treated in some<br />

alternative manner.<br />

In Germany, the “Commercial <strong>Waste</strong>s Ordinance, 2002” came into force on 1 st<br />

January 2003, and provide a minimum separation requirement for pre-treatment<br />

facilities receiving both municipal and commercial wastes, including specific<br />

construction and demolition wastes. To facilitate high levels <strong>of</strong> recovery, Section 8,<br />

Paragraph 1 <strong>of</strong> the Ordinance specifies a number <strong>of</strong> wastes which should be held,<br />

stored, collected and hauled for recovery, separately. These wastes are: paper and<br />

card, glass, plastic, metals and biowaste. The recovery quota is a minimum <strong>of</strong> 85% by<br />

weight over a calendar year, and applies to the wide range <strong>of</strong> waste streams<br />

mentioned in the Annex.<br />

59.8 Levels <strong>of</strong> Achievement for Construction and Demolition<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>s<br />

Many countries report high rates <strong>of</strong> recycling for construction and demolition wastes.<br />

Statistical data tends, however, to be <strong>of</strong> a less good quality than for, for example,<br />

household waste, and many countries make provision for differing ranges <strong>of</strong> recovery<br />

activity.<br />

In the Netherlands, the general policy and framework for waste management is laid<br />

down in the Landelijk Afvalbeheerplan (National <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan). This<br />

describes the general rules for all aspect <strong>of</strong> waste management, from collection to<br />

final disposal, specifying the minimum treatment requirements for each waste<br />

stream. For example, it specifies that, as a minimum, inert C&D waste must be<br />

treated to achieve material recycling. The “Regeling niet-herbruikbaar en niet-<br />

29/09/09


verbrandbaar bouw- en sloopafval” (Regulation on non-recyclable and noncombustible<br />

C&D waste) prescribes that recyclable and combustible C&D waste<br />

cannot be landfilled. C&D waste is defined as non-recyclable and non-combustible if<br />

the >60 mm fraction contains more than 85% <strong>of</strong> the following materials:<br />

891<br />

• Contaminated stony material<br />

• EPS insulated concrete<br />

• Thermal/acoustic insulation material based on minerals<br />

• Tar and bitumen ro<strong>of</strong> material<br />

• S<strong>of</strong>t stony material<br />

• Preserved wood based on “Wolman salts” (Cu, Cr, As)<br />

• Glass<br />

• Non-separable combinations made <strong>of</strong> at least 50% <strong>of</strong> the above materials<br />

For demolition the “Asbestbesluit” (Asbestos Regulations) require the separate<br />

removal and collection <strong>of</strong> asbestos. The “Regeling scheiden en gescheiden houden”<br />

(<strong>Waste</strong> Separation and Storage Regulations) require the separation at source <strong>of</strong><br />

hazardous waste.<br />

In the Netherlands, recyclable/reusable wastes from construction and demolition<br />

have been banned from landfill since 1997. These wastes include masonry &<br />

concrete rubble, metals, untreated wood, paper and cardboard etc. Currently, about<br />

95% <strong>of</strong> all C&D waste is recovered.<br />

In Germany unsorted construction and demolition wastes have been banned from<br />

landfill sites since 2001. The Closed Substance Cycle and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act<br />

was an overarching legislative development in waste management in Germany,<br />

coming into force in September 1996. Its aim was to make producers and<br />

consumers radically rethink approaches to waste: “integrating product responsibility<br />

through economic decision-making process, with the aim <strong>of</strong> building a life cycle<br />

economy that avoids waste generation”. Developing from this, and in response to<br />

pressures to improve recycling and recovery performance, a number <strong>of</strong> other<br />

regulations have come into force, two <strong>of</strong> which are focused on here:<br />

• Commercial <strong>Waste</strong>s Ordinance 2002<br />

• <strong>Waste</strong> Wood Ordinance 2002<br />

Commercial <strong>Waste</strong>s Ordinance 2002<br />

The German Regulations, the “Commercial <strong>Waste</strong>s Ordinance, 2002” came into force<br />

on 1 st January 2003, and provide a minimum separation requirement for pretreatment<br />

facilities receiving both municipal and commercial wastes, including<br />

specific construction and demolition wastes. To facilitate high levels <strong>of</strong> recovery,<br />

Section 8, Paragraph 1 <strong>of</strong> the Ordinance specifies a number <strong>of</strong> wastes which should<br />

be held, stored, collected and hauled for recovery, separately. These wastes are: (i)<br />

glass, (ii) plastic, (iii) metals, (v) concrete, bricks, ceramics (or a mixture <strong>of</strong> these).<br />

The Ordinance provides a derogation from this separation, on the basis that these<br />

waste streams can only be mixed with those set in the Annex to the Ordinance, and<br />

that the initial quantity and purity <strong>of</strong> the these five categories <strong>of</strong> input waste streams<br />

are produced as separated streams for substance, or energy recovery (unless it can<br />

be demonstrated that there is a technical reason why this is not possible).<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The recovery quota is a minimum <strong>of</strong> 85% by weight over a calendar year, and applies<br />

to the wide range <strong>of</strong> waste streams mentioned in the Annex (not containing, or<br />

contaminated by dangerous substances).<br />

According to the Ordinance, waste streams at pretreatment facilities should be<br />

separated to meet the 85% minimum recovery target (quota). A pretreatment facilty<br />

can be defined as such if the wastes in question undergo pre-treatment prior to<br />

substance or energy recovery. Examples <strong>of</strong> pretreatment processes given are sorting,<br />

crushing, compacting, or pelletizing. Though not stated in the Ordinance, for<br />

illustration, an example <strong>of</strong> substance recovery would be the use <strong>of</strong><br />

separated/pelletised plastics used in a plastic moulding process.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Wood Ordinance<br />

In March 2003, the <strong>Waste</strong> Wood Ordinance came into force. The legal framework <strong>of</strong><br />

the Ordinance divides waste wood into four categories, according to pollutant type.<br />

Certain energy recovery or material recycling processes are only admissible for<br />

individual or multiple waste wood categories. Recovery or recycling applies to all<br />

categories except contaminated wood, which must be thermally treated (incinerated).<br />

In addition, the dumping <strong>of</strong> waste wood on landfill sites is prohibited.<br />

In Austria, the 1993 “Ordinance on the Separation <strong>of</strong> Materials Generated during<br />

Construction” requires that groups <strong>of</strong> materials (mineral construction waste,<br />

excavated soil, concrete waste, broken asphalt, wood, metal and plastic waste, as<br />

well as construction site waste) must be separated if they exceed certain threshold<br />

levels. Since this Ordinance entered into force, the recycling has been increased from<br />

the original level <strong>of</strong> 15 per cent (1985) to more than 70 per cent today.<br />

59.9 Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Targets<br />

The Flemish-speaking region <strong>of</strong> Flanders has a population <strong>of</strong> 6 million living in 2.4<br />

million households. It is divided into five provinces and subdivided into 308<br />

municipalities. In its municipal waste management plan 1997-2001, OVAM, the<br />

public waste agency <strong>of</strong> Flanders, set the following targets for the generation <strong>of</strong><br />

residual waste:<br />

892<br />

� 1998: 225 kg per person<br />

� 2001: 220 kg per person<br />

� 2006: 200 kg per person<br />

� 2010: 150kg per person<br />

Success in meeting and exceeding these targets during the plan period led to the<br />

targets being revised and further tightened in the 2003-2007 waste management<br />

plan. The revised targets are:<br />

� 2003: 180 kg per person<br />

� 2005: 165 kg per person<br />

� 2007: 150 kg per person<br />

Figure 59-10 below shows the residual waste per capita against targets from 1991 to<br />

2002 with the targets from 1998 to 2007.<br />

29/09/09


Figure 59-10: Flanders Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Reduction Targets and Actual Quantities<br />

Source: David Davies Associates (2003) High Diversion <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>: Is It Achievable? Resource<br />

Recovery Forum<br />

More recent data obtained suggests that residual waste per capita dropped to 159 kg<br />

per person by 2004, a figure below the 2005 target level (see Figure 59-11). 161 <strong>of</strong><br />

the 308 municipalities were below the 150 kg per person level (the 2007 target) in<br />

2004. 1106<br />

In calculating the targets, residual waste is defined as not recycling/composting. The<br />

quantities included in the residual figure includes waste that is incinerated. The total<br />

quantities <strong>of</strong> landfilled waste have fallen substantially over the period from 1.13<br />

million tonnes (43% <strong>of</strong> waste arisings) in 1993 to 147,000 tonnes (4% <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

arisings) in 2002. While quantities <strong>of</strong> waste incinerated have remained relatively<br />

constant (821,000 tonnes [31%] in 1993 compared to 868,000 tonnes [26%] in<br />

2002. 1107<br />

1106 Julie Hill, Hannah Hislop, Charlotte Steel and Ben Shaw (2006) An <strong>International</strong> Survey <strong>of</strong> Zero<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Initiatives, Green Alliance.<br />

1107 David Davies Associates (2003) High Diversion <strong>of</strong> Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>: Is It Achievable? Resource<br />

Recovery Forum.<br />

893<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Figure 59-11: Evolution in Quantities <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong>, Residual <strong>Waste</strong>, and<br />

Separately Collected <strong>Waste</strong> (kg per inhabitant)<br />

Source: Danny Willle (2006) The Polluter Pays: Key to Successful Household <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

Presentation to ACR+ Conference, Dublin Castle, 19th May 2006.<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> waste prevention the question is: to what degree has the per capita<br />

residual waste target reduced arisings versus simply stimulating greater recovery<br />

from the waste stream? The data suggests that the reduction in residual waste per<br />

capita has come substantially from an increase in recycling. This is shown in Figure<br />

59-11 above.<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Arisings grew by an average <strong>of</strong> 2.9% per annum over the period 1991 – 2002.<br />

However, in the period since 1998, when the first target was introduced, the growth in<br />

arisings has slowed considerably. In the 1998-2004 period, the line <strong>of</strong> best fit<br />

suggests an average growth rate <strong>of</strong> 0.42%, though the correlation <strong>of</strong> this fit is poor. In<br />

the period 2000-2004, the line <strong>of</strong> best fit actually suggests a decrease <strong>of</strong> 0.44% per<br />

annum, though again, the correlation is poor, and inspection by eye suggests zero net<br />

growth over the period.<br />

While the measures taken by OVAM have clearly not reduced overall arisings in<br />

absolute terms, the question can be asked as to whether the rate <strong>of</strong> growth might<br />

have been different in a counterfactual scenario. This is difficult to say, but if the<br />

trend from 1991-2002 had continued from 1998, the arisings per inhabitant would<br />

have been 628kg per inhabitant by 2004. The policy could, under this assumption,<br />

have been responsible for a 10.8% reduction in overall waste quantities over the 6<br />

year period.<br />

Even here, however, the matter is not so clear. Generally, the pre-1998 evolution<br />

shows that prior to this date, overall waste arisings were increasing as recycling rates<br />

improved. This may well have been due to the roll out <strong>of</strong> biowaste collections to<br />

households, generating ‘above background’ growth rates. Notwithstanding this fact,<br />

894<br />

29/09/09


there does appear to have been a slowing in the rate <strong>of</strong> growth, though <strong>of</strong> course, one<br />

could not, unequivocally, attribute this change to this policy alone. 1108<br />

It is worth stating that the setting <strong>of</strong> residual waste targets alone cannot be held to be<br />

responsible for the reduction in residual waste that has been observed in Flanders.<br />

The targets form part <strong>of</strong> an integrated package <strong>of</strong> initiatives which include:<br />

895<br />

� implementing awareness and information campaigns (possibly with specific<br />

target groups in mind, such as schools);<br />

� drafting municipal environmental covenants or cooperation agreements<br />

between local authorities and the Flemish region;<br />

� financial aid for initiatives pertaining to waste prevention and reuse, and<br />

developing a collection and processing infrastructure for the separated<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> municipal waste;<br />

� imposing environmental taxes on the incineration and landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste;<br />

� consultation on policy relating to appropriate environmental permits;<br />

� systematically and consistently applying the ‘the polluter pays’ principle;<br />

� implementing acceptance and take-back obligations, based on the principle <strong>of</strong><br />

producer responsibility;<br />

� implementing and applying landfilling and incineration bans;<br />

� monitoring and enforcing the observance <strong>of</strong> rules and regulations. 1109<br />

Although a wide range <strong>of</strong> initiatives has been employed, the importance <strong>of</strong> setting a<br />

target should not be underestimated. The target provided a clear focus for action,<br />

and the need or desire to meet the target was integral to the successful<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> the above initiatives. OVAM also enforced the target through the<br />

application <strong>of</strong> upper target limits which no single municipality was allowed to exceed.<br />

These were 220kg/per inhabitant in 2003 and 200kg/per inhabitant in 2005. In<br />

addition local authorities are encouraged to reduce residual waste through signing<br />

voluntary ‘Environmental agreements or covenants’. These link the results obtained<br />

to the provision <strong>of</strong> financial support which is financed through taxes on the landfilling<br />

and incineration <strong>of</strong> waste. 1110<br />

1108 Parent et al (2004) attribute some <strong>of</strong> the decrease in waste growth to an increase in reuse centres<br />

and a decrease in the total quantity <strong>of</strong> packaging, due mainly to lightweighting <strong>of</strong> packaging design<br />

(see Frank Parent, Luc Vanacker, Anne Vandeputte, Danny Wille (2004) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

in Flanders - Experiences and Challenges, Public <strong>Waste</strong> Agency <strong>of</strong> Flanders, April 2004).<br />

1109 Frank Parent, Luc Vanacker, Anne Vandeputte, Danny Wille (2004) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

in Flanders - Experiences and Challenges, Public <strong>Waste</strong> Agency <strong>of</strong> Flanders, April 2004.<br />

1110 Frank Parent, Luc Vanacker, Anne Vandeputte, Danny Wille (2004) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

in Flanders - Experiences and Challenges, Public <strong>Waste</strong> Agency <strong>of</strong> Flanders, April 2004.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


59.9.1 Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Levy<br />

In Wallonia (Belgium), the regional Government introduced a novel instrument in<br />

which the local authorities were subjected to a residual waste levy. In essence, the<br />

levy specified a quantity <strong>of</strong> residual waste per inhabitant which could be generated<br />

free <strong>of</strong> any levy. For those authorities whose generation <strong>of</strong> residual waste exceeded<br />

this ‘quota’, a levy on the excess was applied. The quota was reduced over time to<br />

encourage local authorities to reduce the residual waste generated.<br />

In Wallonia, this had the effect, amongst other things, <strong>of</strong> encouraging widespread<br />

dissemination <strong>of</strong> pay-by-use charging. The development in the uptake <strong>of</strong> charging<br />

schemes is shown clearly in Figure 59-12 below.<br />

Residual waste levies applied only to waste quantities exceeding a specified target<br />

level imply that where waste quantities fall below this level, there is no further<br />

motivation for residual waste reduction.<br />

In principle, a residual waste levy could be used to create incentives for local<br />

authorities to both:<br />

896<br />

29/09/09<br />

a) not exceed a set annual waste per household target; and<br />

b) reduce annual waste per household arisings as much as possible below this<br />

target.<br />

It is suggested here that there are two ways <strong>of</strong> doing this:<br />

a) By setting a pre-determined target and charging local authorities who exceed<br />

the target level and refunding the revenue to those who fall below it. By using<br />

this approach <strong>of</strong> ‘rebating revenue’, those doing better are rewarded with the<br />

penalty revenue gained from those doing worse; or<br />

b) By setting the level against which rebates are paid at the average level <strong>of</strong><br />

performance <strong>of</strong> the authorities. Those above would be charged a predetermined<br />

levy, with the overall revenue refunded to those who are below the<br />

average level in proportion to how far below they are.<br />

59.9.1.1 Pre-determined Target<br />

The first approach sets targets to continuously improve. Critical to the success <strong>of</strong> the<br />

levy would be setting the fines/rebates at a level that would provide sufficient<br />

incentive for authorities to take action without being unduly punitive for authorities<br />

that fail to reach the target levels.<br />

On the other hand, since the levy is fiscally neutral, with rebates equalling fines, then<br />

it seems possible that the marginal incentive could be slightly higher than in cases<br />

where no such rebating system was in place. Although the level <strong>of</strong> any levy would<br />

have to be announced in advance, it seems possible that it (and possibly the targets<br />

themselves) could be periodically reviewed so as to give greater or weaker incentives,<br />

as appropriate, to ensure targets were met without generating unduly large costs or<br />

benefits to specific authorities.


Figure 59-12: Residual <strong>Waste</strong> per Inhabitant Related to Charge Scheme<br />

Note: OMB (kg/hab.an) = Residual <strong>Waste</strong> per Inhabitant per Year<br />

59.9.1.2 Levy Based on Average Residual Quantities<br />

The second approach generates a relatively unpredictable target, but it has the merit<br />

<strong>of</strong> avoiding the setting <strong>of</strong> targets which prove to be impossible to achieve (under<br />

existing frameworks). Authorities would have an incentive always to be operating with<br />

above average performance (lower quantities <strong>of</strong> residual waste than others) so as to<br />

avoid charges and receive refunds. This ought to imply that the average residual<br />

waste per household trends continuously downwards.<br />

In a slightly dystopian outcome, this approach may promote cross-authority<br />

cooperation to maintain relatively conservative and constant quantities <strong>of</strong> residual<br />

waste arisings, but even here, there would be a considerable incentive to cheat, or to<br />

stay out <strong>of</strong> such a collusive arrangement.<br />

The target is set as the annual average quantity <strong>of</strong> residual waste per household and<br />

establishes accountability for every authority because evidently the average is, by<br />

definition, attainable. More interesting variants could apply levies on the excess<br />

which increase as the magnitude <strong>of</strong> the excess changes.<br />

59.9.2 Scenario Examples<br />

In Table 59-5, we show how such a levy might function in the case where there are 4<br />

authorities, two whose arisings exceed the target level (expressed in terms <strong>of</strong> kg per<br />

inhabitant per annum – the figures are indicative only) and two who have residual<br />

waste quantities below the target level.<br />

897<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Red= No scheme<br />

Yellow = Volume-based<br />

Grey = Weight-based<br />

Development <strong>of</strong> Charging Scheme Types


Table 59-5: Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Levy, Pre-set Target @ 300kg/inh<br />

Residual waste<br />

per inhabitant<br />

300kg<br />

Assume that:<br />

898<br />

29/09/09<br />

Authority A<br />

Authority B<br />

Excess <strong>of</strong><br />

100kg/inh<br />

Authority C<br />

• Authority A has 75,000 households;<br />

• Authority B has 50,000 households;<br />

• Authority C has 60,000 households; and<br />

• Authority D has 100,000 households.<br />

Excess <strong>of</strong><br />

60kg/inh<br />

Authority D<br />

Assume also that the levy is set at €30 per tonne. Then:<br />

Below target by<br />

75kg/inh<br />

Below target by<br />

100kg/inh<br />

• Authority A has a total excess <strong>of</strong> residual waste = 75,000 x 100kg = 7,500<br />

tonnes. It pays 7,500 * €30 = €225,000<br />

• Authority B has a total excess <strong>of</strong> residual waste = 50,000 x 60kg = 3,000<br />

tonnes. It pays 3,000 x €30 = €90,000.<br />

This gives a total <strong>of</strong> levy revenue <strong>of</strong> €315,000. Those that do better than target would<br />

receive this revenue (net <strong>of</strong> administrative costs, here assumed to be zero for the<br />

sake <strong>of</strong> simplicity). Hence<br />

• Authority C has a total ‘deficit’ <strong>of</strong> residual waste = 60,000 x 75kg = 4,500<br />

tonnes;<br />

• Authority D has a total ‘deficit’ <strong>of</strong> residual waste = 100,000 x 100kg = 7,500<br />

tonnes;


899<br />

• The total ‘better than target’ performance amounts to 12,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> which<br />

Authority C is responsible for (4,500/12,000) = 37.5%, and Authority D is<br />

responsible for (7,500/12,000) = 62.5%;<br />

• Consequently:<br />

o Authority C receives 37.5% x €315,000 = €118,125; and<br />

o Authority D receives 62.5% x €315,000 = €196,875<br />

In the round, the approach is revenue neutral. It implies transfers from authorities<br />

which do well to authorities which do less well.<br />

In the case where the average is used as the target, then from the same figure:<br />

• Authority A produces 400kg/inh;<br />

• Authority B produces 360kg/inh;<br />

• Authority C produces 225kg/inh; and<br />

• Authority D produces 200kg/inh.<br />

Then the weighted average is 285.96 kg/inh. It can be seen that the same calculation<br />

in terms <strong>of</strong> levies and rebates would generate similar results, but in this case, the<br />

quantum <strong>of</strong> revenue would be greater (the excesses are larger), so the rebates would<br />

be greater also.<br />

What would clearly be different in the two examples is how the impact <strong>of</strong> the levy<br />

would change over time. Where the target is pre-determined, then care would be<br />

needed to ensure that the targets were achievable. If they are too challenging, then<br />

the consequence might be that authorities simply pay the levy and there is no<br />

recipient <strong>of</strong> the rebate. This could also be the outcome if the levy is set too low (so<br />

that the cost <strong>of</strong> taking action exceeds that <strong>of</strong> doing nothing).<br />

59.10 Summary<br />

There appears to be plenty <strong>of</strong> scope for revising key targets upwards in Ireland. In<br />

respect <strong>of</strong> waste prevention, we would caution against setting these in Ireland at<br />

present, not least because there remain problems with past data sets. In particular:<br />

• it appears that the boundary between household and non-household waste is<br />

not so sharply distinguished. This means that the underlying trends in the one<br />

and the other are not so straightforward to discern;<br />

• the quantities <strong>of</strong> household waste generated are distorted by factors such as<br />

the number <strong>of</strong> households not currently having their waste collected and the<br />

likely prevalence <strong>of</strong> backyard burning; and<br />

• the fact that in respect <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition waste, the data are<br />

generally <strong>of</strong> poor quality.<br />

That does not mean that such targets should not be set in future.<br />

A possible way <strong>of</strong> integrating a recycling target alongside a driver for waste prevention<br />

is a target on ‘residual’ quantities. We have noted above that this type <strong>of</strong> target is<br />

well-suited to the household waste area because it gives equal status to waste<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


prevention and waste recycling, whilst waste recycling targets tend to underplay, and<br />

sometimes even undermine, waste prevention (especially where garden waste<br />

collections are <strong>of</strong>fered free <strong>of</strong> charge). We recommend this for Ireland.<br />

We did consider that a residual waste target might be appropriate for packaging. We<br />

looked at Irish performance in this regard in Annex 12.0, and noted that it appeared<br />

to be comparatively poor, but also that the data might not be reliable. The data is the<br />

main reason for not pursuing this target. It should be noted that under such a target,<br />

‘self-compliance’ is not possible. All that all producers (major and otherwise) can do is<br />

contribute to the meeting <strong>of</strong> this target as part <strong>of</strong> a collective. This might, in some<br />

respects, make enforcement somewhat more straightforward, especially in the Irish<br />

case where only one compliance scheme exists.<br />

As regards recycling targets, these are proposed in the Main Report.<br />

As regards targets on reducing waste sent to landfill, the EPA’s pre-treatment<br />

requirements should ensure that in due course, no waste which has not undergone<br />

pre-treatment is landfilled.<br />

The potential impact <strong>of</strong> these targets, at least in respect <strong>of</strong> municipal waste, is<br />

discussed below in Annex 63.0.<br />

900<br />

29/09/09


GRANT FUNDING<br />

901<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


60.0 Grant Funding<br />

60.1 Introduction<br />

The public sector is the main source <strong>of</strong> the grant funding, <strong>of</strong>fering financial assistance<br />

to organisations across the public and private sectors. The public sector sources the<br />

funds both from general taxation, and from specific ring-fenced pots <strong>of</strong> money,<br />

derived from particular taxes associated with potential environmentally detrimental<br />

activities, e.g. landfilling. The funds are then used to finance projects which <strong>of</strong>fset<br />

these detrimental activities, or support environmental policy goals.<br />

The OECD suggests:<br />

902<br />

29/09/09<br />

‘The golden rule <strong>of</strong> public funding suggests that governments should support<br />

only those investments that are economically efficient but not financially<br />

viable’. 1111<br />

By following the OECD’s advice, grants should fund projects which can prove that their<br />

reliance upon the funding is not long-term, and that they have the capacity to function<br />

sustainably, i.e. without the grant support, in the future. This generally makes it<br />

important to ensure that the applications for funding demonstrate an ability to stand<br />

on their own feet once grant support falls away. In some cases, revenues may be<br />

used to support specific activities on an ongoing basis, but in these cases, it is not<br />

clear what purpose the ear-marking purpose serves. If there are areas <strong>of</strong> activity<br />

which require ongoing support, presumably in the public sector, then it becomes<br />

unclear why the activity should not be supported through general taxation rather than<br />

ear-marking per se, though clearly, it can be argued that the two are equivalent.<br />

Having looked at the Irish case (Section 60.2), this report seeks to identify current<br />

international examples <strong>of</strong> grant funding (Section 60.4 to Section 60.12). Following<br />

this, the Irish case will be examined and recommendations will be made.<br />

60.2 Grant Funding in Ireland<br />

60.2.1 National Development Plan<br />

In Ireland the co-ordinating structure for the planning <strong>of</strong> government over a<br />

programme period is the National Development Plan (NDP). Historically, over past<br />

programme periods for the NDP, a significant feature <strong>of</strong> the NDP was the co-funding<br />

<strong>of</strong> some programmes and measures with income from the Irish exchequer along with<br />

EU funding. This has significantly reduced in the latest NDP period (2007-2013), in<br />

which an expected €3 billion from the EU Structural Funds was planned for within the<br />

€184 million expenditure planned for priority investment in the period.<br />

1111 OECD (2007) Handbook for Appraisal <strong>of</strong> Environmental Projects Financed from Public Funds,<br />

report to OECD by the Task Force for the Implementation <strong>of</strong> the Environmental Action Programme,<br />

Available: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/10/63/38786197.pdf


NDP 2000-2006<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> management & waste infrastructure development planning have been<br />

included within the NDP in regional programmes in the past, to facilitate funding <strong>of</strong><br />

waste management activities at regional & local levels. The National Development<br />

Plan website outlines the mechanism through which the allocation <strong>of</strong> funds was<br />

administered, in particular where receipt <strong>of</strong> funding is negotiated and agreed with the<br />

EU; 1112<br />

903<br />

“To draw down E.U. Structural Funds, each Member State has to draw up and<br />

submit a plan setting out its investment priorities for the funding period….in<br />

Ireland’s case, the National Development Plan (NDP)…. (the subsequent) …<br />

agreement resulted in a Community Support Framework (CSF.)…”<br />

The NDP and the CSF form the basis <strong>of</strong> the implementation <strong>of</strong> the agreement for EU<br />

funding.<br />

Within the previous NDP (2000-2006), there were two regional assemblies which<br />

were the administrative bodies within which funding was administered through<br />

regional programmes; the Border, Midland & Western (BMW) assembly and the<br />

Southern & Eastern (S & E) assembly. The regionalisation arrangements negotiated<br />

by Ireland in the context <strong>of</strong> the Agenda 2000 Agreement resulted in the designation<br />

<strong>of</strong> two regions in Ireland for Structural Funds Purposes:<br />

� The Southern and Eastern Region (S&E Region) which will qualify for a six year<br />

phasing out regime for Objective 1 Structural Funds up to the end <strong>of</strong> 2005,<br />

and<br />

� The Border, Midland and Western Region (BMW Region) which has retained<br />

Objective 1 status for Structural Funds for the full period to 2006.<br />

Following this designation, two new Regional Assemblies where established and came<br />

into effect on the 21st July 1999 under the Local Government Act, 1991 (Regional<br />

Authorities) (Establishment) Order, 1999. The Assemblies are comprised <strong>of</strong><br />

nominated elected representatives <strong>of</strong> the regional authorities within their Region. The<br />

principal functions <strong>of</strong> the Regional Assemblies are:<br />

� To promote the co-ordination <strong>of</strong> public services in the Southern and Eastern<br />

Region<br />

� To manage the Southern and Eastern Regional Operational Programme under<br />

the National Development Plan (2000-2006)<br />

� Monitor and make proposals in relation to the general impact <strong>of</strong> their regions<br />

<strong>of</strong> all E.U. Programmes <strong>of</strong> assistance under the Community Support<br />

Framework<br />

1112 National Development Plan (2009) National Development Plan Website, Available:<br />

http://www.ndp.ie/viewdoc.asp?fn=/documents/eu_structural_funds/overview/structural_funds.htm<br />

&mn=euso&nID=3<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


904<br />

� Make public bodies aware <strong>of</strong> the regional implications <strong>of</strong> their policies, plans<br />

and activities<br />

The BMW and S & E assemblies operated four sub-programmes in 2000-2006 <strong>of</strong><br />

which one was local infrastructure. This was divided into seven measures <strong>of</strong> which<br />

one was waste management. The following came under the remit <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management:<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> recovery infrastructure for municipal waste, to be developed in<br />

accordance with regional and local <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plans;<br />

� Hazardous waste landfill capacity, to be provided in accordance with the<br />

National Hazardous <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Plan. 1113<br />

In the 2000-2006 period, the funding available for these activities was €370.49<br />

million in the BMW region and €621.18 million in the S & E region. This is an<br />

extremely significant sum.<br />

NDP 2007-2013<br />

Within the 2007-2013 programme period for the NDP, € 5.8 billion will be in the<br />

Environmental Services area, <strong>of</strong> which € 753 million will be within the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Sub Programme <strong>of</strong> the NDP’s Economic Infrastructure Priority. In the<br />

Irish context, this is a significant sum <strong>of</strong> money. The NDP indicates that the funds are<br />

expected to ‘address the problems associated with legacy landfills; support, through<br />

private investment, the development <strong>of</strong> thermal treatment plants to reduce landfill<br />

usage, and promote greater use <strong>of</strong> recycling and recovery.’<br />

Although some €3 billion is expected to come from EU funds in the latest NDP period,<br />

the S&E Region’s Operational Programme makes no reference to waste management<br />

within its Programme whilst the BMW Region’s Operational Programme is concerned<br />

with waste only in terms <strong>of</strong> assisting in the protection <strong>of</strong> groundwaste (through<br />

managing slurries).<br />

60.2.2 <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Infrastructure Capital Grant Scheme<br />

In March 2002, within the context <strong>of</strong> the waste programme/ statement document,<br />

“Preventing and Recycling <strong>Waste</strong>: Delivering Change”, a €127m capital grant scheme<br />

was launched by Mr. Noel Dempsey, T.D., Minister for the Environment and Local<br />

Government under the National Development Plan. The scheme, ‘The <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Infrastructure Capital Grants Scheme’ was launched as part <strong>of</strong> the<br />

National Development Plan 2000-2006. The scheme was co-funded by the Irish<br />

Exchequer and by the EU from the European Regional Development Fund. Local<br />

1113 National Development Plan (2009) National Development Plan Website, Available:<br />

http://www.ndp.ie/viewdoc.asp?fn=/documents/eu_structural_funds/overview/structural_funds.htm<br />

&mn=euso&nID=3<br />

29/09/09


authority projects approved for assistance under the Scheme were grant aided at the<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> up to 75% <strong>of</strong> eligible costs. 1114<br />

The National Development Plan website highlights some examples <strong>of</strong> development<br />

funded under the ‘<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Infrastructure Capital Grants Scheme’. 1115<br />

� Sandy Sandy Road, Road, Galway Galway –Materials Materials Recovery Recovery Facility Facility Facility development development (Galway (Galway County ounty<br />

Council Council) Council Council)<br />

)<br />

905<br />

This facility recovers dry recyclable materials, such as cardboard, paper, plastic,<br />

tetra pak and food and beverage cans which are collected from over 18,000<br />

households in Galway City through the source separated collection system.<br />

Additional facilities are also provided for the reception <strong>of</strong> bulky household waste<br />

items, with a view to waste recovery and onward transfer to recycling companies.<br />

The approved costs are €1,308,620 with €981,465 provided by grant aid.<br />

� Carrowbrowne, Co. Galway - Composting facility development (Galway<br />

County Council)<br />

Composting facility - This facility is designed to process 9,500 tonnes <strong>of</strong> green<br />

and household organic waste which is collected in the brown bins issued to over<br />

18,000 households in the city and from the city's parks. The compost will be used<br />

as soil enricher in the city’s parks and open spaces and may also be made<br />

available to householders. The operational cost <strong>of</strong> the scheme is recovered from<br />

each householder through an annual refuse charge in accordance with the<br />

Polluter Pays Principle. The approved costs are €2,285,253 with €1,713,940<br />

provided by grant aid.<br />

� North Stand, Dublin 3 – Development <strong>of</strong> a Civic Amenity site (Dublin City<br />

Council)<br />

Dublin City Council received a grant <strong>of</strong> €285,262 for a Civic Amenity Site at<br />

Aldborough Parade- Shamrock Terrace, in the North Strand. Of this, €142,631 <strong>of</strong><br />

the grant was funded by the Irish Exchequer, with a matching amount <strong>of</strong><br />

€142,631 being funded by the EU from the European Regional Development<br />

Fund. The material accepted at the Civic Amenity facility is a combination <strong>of</strong><br />

domestic recyclable materials and civic amenity bulky wastes. No commercial<br />

waste is accepted.<br />

1114 National Development Plan (2009) National Development Plan Website, Available:<br />

http://www.ndp.ie/viewdoc.asp?DocID=485<br />

1115 National Development Plan (2009) National Development Plan Website, Available:<br />

http://www.ndp.ie/viewdoc.asp?fn=/documents/GuideToFunding/default.asp?v=ProgID=1,RegionID=<br />

1,SubProgID=4,MeasureID=3&mn=guij<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


906<br />

The site accepts the following materials: glass, textiles & clothing, paper,<br />

cardboard, plastics, aluminium & steel, cans, wood, brown goods (typically<br />

furniture), white goods (refrigerators, freezers, washing machines etc), rubble &<br />

steel (small quantities), household electrical & IT goods (TVs computers etc),<br />

bulky wastes (mattresses, household DIY waste) and household hazardous waste<br />

(bleach, paint, fluorescent tubes, etc). The facility was <strong>of</strong>ficially opened in March<br />

2003.<br />

The National Development Plan website outlines the review and monitoring structures<br />

in place to assess the progress and outcome <strong>of</strong> the various sub programmes.<br />

29/09/09<br />

While, overall responsibility for the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Plan rests with the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Finance, each Operational Programme is administered by a<br />

Managing Authority. The authority, in turn, delegates the implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

individual measures to an Implementing Body (in most cases a Government<br />

<strong>Department</strong> or State Agency). Each programme is monitored by a Monitoring<br />

Committee, comprising representatives from the Government <strong>Department</strong> or<br />

State Agency responsible for implementing the measure, the Social Partners<br />

and the Managing Authority. These committees meet twice a year to review<br />

progress in the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Operational Programmes. 1116<br />

Once an evaluation report is complete, the Managing Authority for the programme<br />

concerned submits the report for discussion to the operational programme<br />

monitoring committee. The Monitoring Committee is required to consider and take<br />

a position on all recommendations made in the evaluation (It does not, <strong>of</strong> course,<br />

have to accept the recommendations). The Managing Authority is required to<br />

report back to the committee on progress made in implementing agreed<br />

recommendations. 1117<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Infrastructure Capital Grants Scheme, which was launched<br />

in 2002 and under which over €100m was allocated in grant assistance to local<br />

authorities, closed to new applications in 2008. This scheme assisted in the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> the current nationwide network <strong>of</strong> almost 2,000 bring banks and<br />

more than 80 civic amenity sites.<br />

60.2.3 <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Capital Grant Scheme<br />

In July 2008, with the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Infrastructure Capital Grants<br />

Schemehaving closed, the <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Capital Grant Scheme was launched with<br />

the aim <strong>of</strong> providing assistance in meeting the Landfill Directive diversion targets.<br />

Under this scheme grant funding <strong>of</strong> up to 85% is available towards projects designed<br />

to increase the biological treatment <strong>of</strong> waste. This is an increase from 75% which had<br />

1116 National Development Plan (2009) National Development Plan Website, Available:<br />

http://www.eustructuralfunds.ie/viewdoc.asp?fn=%2Fdocuments%2Foverview%2Fevaluation.htm&mn<br />

=ovec&nID=5<br />

1117 National Development Plan (2009) National Development Plan Website, Available:<br />

http://www.eustructuralfunds.ie/viewdoc.asp?fn=%2Fdocuments%2Foverview%2Fevaluation.htm&mn<br />

=ovec&nID=5


previously been available for such projects. In 2008, €24 million was made available<br />

to local authorities under the scheme.<br />

60.2.4 The Environment Fund<br />

In addition to the position that exists for waste infrastructure development within NDP<br />

planning, the regulatory mechanism <strong>of</strong> the Environment Fund exists as a source <strong>of</strong><br />

funding for waste management measures.<br />

Provision for the creation <strong>of</strong> the Environment Fund was made through the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> (Amendment) Act 2001. Section 12 <strong>of</strong> the 2001 Act makes<br />

amendments to the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act 1996 through providing for the insertion<br />

<strong>of</strong> Section 74 into the 1996 Act.<br />

The Environment Fund comprises revenues from the landfill levy and the plastic bag<br />

levy, although there is potential for money to be contributed to the fund from the<br />

exchequer - if or when agreement is made with the Minister for Finance. It is managed<br />

and controlled by the Minister for the Environment and Local Government and can be<br />

utilised for the following purposes: 1118<br />

907<br />

� schemes to prevent/reduce waste<br />

� waste recovery activities<br />

� research & development into waste management<br />

� production, distribution or sale <strong>of</strong> products deemed to be less harmful to the<br />

environment than other similar products<br />

� development <strong>of</strong> producer initiatives to prevent/reduce waste arising from their<br />

activities<br />

� implementation <strong>of</strong> waste management plans<br />

� enforcement <strong>of</strong> the provisions <strong>of</strong> any enactment relating to waste<br />

management, prevention <strong>of</strong> litter or protection <strong>of</strong> the environment<br />

� partnership projects, that involve local authorities, to improve the quality <strong>of</strong> the<br />

environment for particular local communities<br />

� promotion <strong>of</strong> awareness <strong>of</strong> the need to protect the environment, including<br />

national and regional campaigns<br />

� promotion /support <strong>of</strong> education and training to assist achievement <strong>of</strong><br />

campaign objectives<br />

� resources (human or material) to enable education and training to be carried<br />

out<br />

1118 <strong>Department</strong> for the Environment, Heritage and Local Government (2009) Environment Fund<br />

Website Page, Available: http://www.environ.ie/en/Environment/<strong>Waste</strong>/EnvironmentFund/<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


908<br />

� initiatives undertaken by community groups and others for protection <strong>of</strong> the<br />

environment such other purposes for protection <strong>of</strong> the environment as may be<br />

prescribed by the Minister in regulations.<br />

Funding is allocated via a two tier process. It is allocated for use, within the<br />

boundaries listed above, to the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment. It is then down to the<br />

Minister to pass individual applications for funding. Funding very <strong>of</strong>ten runs over a 3<br />

year contract so that schemes periodically require authorisation by the Minister.<br />

These are <strong>of</strong>ten informed by the direction the EPA are taking, for example a recent<br />

increase towards research and development led to new funding contracts being<br />

drawn up.<br />

Provision <strong>of</strong> money from the Environment Fund is described below, as outlined by the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment in correspondence: 1119<br />

29/09/09<br />

Sections within the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment, Heritage & Local Government<br />

may apply to the Environment Fund Administrator seeking an allocation from<br />

the Fund for projects which fall within the remit <strong>of</strong> the Act - funding is not<br />

made directly available from the Fund to individual applicants and there is no<br />

mechanism by which applicants may apply for funding from the Environment<br />

Fund. Where allocations to sections within the <strong>Department</strong> are approved, it<br />

is up to the individual <strong>Department</strong>al section concerned to invite applications<br />

for projects within the remit <strong>of</strong> their sectional work area.<br />

The requests from <strong>Department</strong>al sections for an allocation from the<br />

Environment Fund are assessed by the Fund Administrator and submitted to<br />

the Minister for approval. Allocations are prioritised on the basis <strong>of</strong> their ability<br />

to contribute to the purposes outlined at (a) to (m) [as given in the legislation].<br />

If these allocations are approved it is up to the individual section concerned<br />

to invite applications for their projects, decide as to the merits <strong>of</strong> individual<br />

applications, set the criteria for awarding funding, evaluate the effectiveness<br />

<strong>of</strong> the money spent , etc.<br />

There is no limit placed by the Environment Fund Administrator on the<br />

maximum grants available for specific projects. However, the various sections<br />

drawing down funding from the Fund may put limits in place that<br />

are appropriate to the grants awarded to specific local schemes/projects<br />

receiving money from the <strong>Department</strong>al sections.<br />

The information available concerning the applications for the fund is limited, but<br />

some can be gleaned from the Environmental Fund Published Accounts which are<br />

currently available since the year the fund was established in 2001 until 2006 (Table<br />

60-1)<br />

1119 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment (2009) Correspondence with C O Grady March 2009.


Table 60-1: Environment Fund Income & Expenditure 2002 - 2006<br />

Income Income<br />

2002 2002 2002 2003 2003 2003 20 2004 20<br />

04 2005 2005 2006<br />

2006<br />

Environmental Levy on the Landfill <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> €17,868,726 €29,359,585 €26,765,514 €27,798,605 €30,750,433<br />

Environmental Levy on Plastic Bags €10,428,413 €12,883,408 €15,278,107 €17,484,551 €19,947,315<br />

Interest on Investments - €71,383 €891,815 €914,525 €1,436,644<br />

Total Income €28,297,139 €28,297,139 €42,314,3 €42,314,376<br />

€42,314,3 €42,314,376<br />

76 €42,935,436<br />

€42,935,436 €42,935,436 €46,197,681 €46,197,681 €52,134,392<br />

€52,134,392<br />

Expenditure<br />

Expenditure<br />

North/South <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Programmes - €945 €83,917 €341,585 €602,438<br />

INTERREG <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Projects - - €250,800 €92,669 €196<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Programme & MDP [Note 1] - - €283,463 €802,042 €1,725,866<br />

Producer Responsibility Initiatives €1,000 €234,327 €61,674 €541,137 €408,304<br />

Environmental Levy Operational Costs €1,828,688 €346,405 €374,601 €480,825 €237,248<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Operational Costs - €96,362 €123,868 €6,530 €59,074<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Including Recycling Projects €2,084,581 €5,625,391 €22,007,645 €7,272,502 €2,242,334<br />

Recycling Operational Costs - €5,000,005 €7,000,200 €7,000,020 €10,000,200<br />

Local Authority Enforcement Initiatives - €741,201 €4,051,313 €8,848,972 €7,774,502<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Infrastructure Operational Costs/ Consultancy - €85,825 - - -<br />

Environment Awareness - €2,465,400 €2,619,155 €4,085,359 €3,649,342<br />

Pollution Control Air/ Climate - €171,828 €332,205 €137,389 €239,595<br />

<strong>International</strong> Conventions / Bodies / Organisations €17,634 €2,373,030 €2,318,268 €2,436,226 €2,497,984<br />

Litter Initiatives - €1,043,482 €1,206,690 €1,044,339 €1,371,716<br />

REACH - - - €14,188 -<br />

Office <strong>of</strong> Environmental Enforcement - €266,509 €861,000 €1,800,000 €2,185,886<br />

EPA R&D - - €7,250,000 €7,000,000 €7,000,000<br />

Water Quality<br />

Comhar - the National Sustainable Development<br />

- €151,052 €193,932 €177,927 €78,974<br />

Partnership - €168,847 €167,623 €102,567 €292,056<br />

Total Expenditure €3,931,903 €3,931,903 €18,770,609<br />

€18,770,609 €18,770,609 €49,186,354<br />

€49,186,354 €49,186,354 €42,184,277 €42,184,277 €40,365, €40,365,715<br />

€40,365, 715<br />

Surplus for the Year €24,365,236 €23,543,767 €23,543,767 -€6,250,918<br />

€6,250,918 €4,013,404 €4,013,404 €11,768,677<br />

€11,768,677<br />

909<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


These show that in the first year <strong>of</strong> the fund, 2001/02, there were four areas which<br />

accounted for the Fund’s expenditure – with one <strong>of</strong> these being the collection costs <strong>of</strong><br />

the levy. Between 2003 and 2006 the expenditure increased from 15 key areas to 18<br />

key areas, with the most recent listed below:<br />

910<br />

29/09/09<br />

� North/South <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Programmes;<br />

� INTERREG <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Projects;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and National Market Development Programmes;<br />

� Producer Responsibility Initiatives;<br />

� Environmental Levy Collection Costs;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention Operational Costs;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> including Recycling Projects;<br />

� Recycling Operational Costs;<br />

� Local Authority Enforcement Initiatives;<br />

� Environment Awareness;<br />

� Pollution Control Air/Climate;<br />

� <strong>International</strong> Conventions/Bodies/Organisations;<br />

� Litter Initiatives;<br />

� REACH;<br />

� Office <strong>of</strong> Environmental Enforcement;<br />

� EPA R&D;<br />

� Water Quality; and<br />

� Comhar – the National Sustainable Development Partnership.<br />

Spending on programmes and measures under the Environment Fund must come<br />

within the remit <strong>of</strong> the legislation governing the Fund. The assessment methodology<br />

and criteria are outlined from correspondence with the <strong>Department</strong>;<br />

Each section is responsible for ensuring that the funding they have been<br />

provided with for subsequent distribution for individual projects complies with<br />

the terms <strong>of</strong> Section 74(9) <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act 1996 (as inserted<br />

by Section 12 <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Amendment) Act 2001) and the<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> (Environment Fund) (Prescribed Payments) Regulations<br />

2003 (SI No. 478 <strong>of</strong> 2003). Therefore there is no single contact point in the<br />

<strong>Department</strong> to supply details on which individual projects are grant-aided from<br />

the Fund. However details <strong>of</strong> the general headings under which funding has


een provided are available in the Environment Fund Accounts, which are<br />

available on the <strong>Department</strong>'s website. 1120<br />

In so far as an application comes within the remit <strong>of</strong> the objectives (a) to (m) as set<br />

out in the amended Act, there is potential for the grant application to be funded.<br />

Further than that, grant approval is given across all waste management areas and<br />

activities, rather than being streamlined or concentrated to the achievement <strong>of</strong> a<br />

narrower set <strong>of</strong> outcomes e.g. achievement <strong>of</strong> the objectives <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Directive.<br />

60.3 Comparison between Funds in UK and Ireland<br />

There is some concern because with similar areas being funded year after year there<br />

may be some reliance from certain organizations upon the fund. Their presumption<br />

that they may be in line to receive a portion <strong>of</strong> the funding does not fall in line with<br />

the, ‘golden rule <strong>of</strong> public funding which suggests that governments should support<br />

only those investments that are economically efficient but not financially viable’. 1121<br />

Funding must be seen to support projects which can prove to be sustainable after the<br />

funding ceases. For this reason, public funding is usually required to be contributed to<br />

by the organization applying for the funding, or a third party.<br />

More information regarding the UK’s Landfill Communities Fund is described in<br />

following sections, but an initial comparison between this funding stream, and<br />

Ireland’s Environmental Fund, is shown in Table 60-2.<br />

60.4 Sources <strong>of</strong> Fund and Size <strong>of</strong> Fund<br />

The following examples show that environmental funding is most commonly made<br />

available through the public sector which finances grants through their central budget<br />

or through environmental taxation. Those funds sourced from taxes are seemingly<br />

those which are ongoing, and those which are funded through the public sector’s<br />

budget are usually for a limited period <strong>of</strong> time, with the amounts available from both<br />

sources being hugely variable.<br />

60.4.1 Environmental Taxation<br />

Revenue from environmental taxes is sometimes ear-marked, or hypothecated, to<br />

form an environmental fund which is used to support environmentally sound actions.<br />

Environmental taxation is one direct source <strong>of</strong> grant funds, and the level <strong>of</strong> taxation<br />

has a bearing upon the size <strong>of</strong> the fund available. Some examples <strong>of</strong> this are set out<br />

below.<br />

1120 <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment (2009) Correspondence with C O Grady March 2009.<br />

1121 OECD (2007) Handbook for Appraisal <strong>of</strong> Environmental Projects Financed from Public Funds,<br />

report to OECD by the Task Force for the Implementation <strong>of</strong> the Environmental Action Programme,<br />

Available: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/10/63/38786197.pdf<br />

911<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 60-2: Comparison between the UK and Irish Landfill Levy Fund<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> times you can<br />

apply to the fund<br />

Geographical area to<br />

which the fund applies<br />

Governance structure<br />

Who can apply?<br />

Can 100% funding be<br />

applied for?<br />

The The UK UK Landfill Landfill Communities Communities Fund Fund (LCF)<br />

(LCF)<br />

912<br />

29/09/09<br />

Ireland’s Ireland’s Environment<br />

Environment<br />

Environment<br />

Fund<br />

Fund<br />

There is no information<br />

available on any time<br />

limitations which may be<br />

applicable to this fund.<br />

This fund is administered<br />

centrally and public and<br />

private bodies all over<br />

Ireland can apply to the<br />

Fund.<br />

It is managed and<br />

controlled centrally by the<br />

Minister for the<br />

Environment and Local<br />

Government<br />

Public and private bodies<br />

can apply to the Fund<br />

Information on funding<br />

guidelines are not clear<br />

UK’s UK’s UK’s Landfill Landfill Landfill Communities<br />

Communities<br />

Communities<br />

Fund<br />

Fund<br />

This varies according to<br />

which Distributive<br />

Environmental Body (DEB)<br />

is applied to. For example,<br />

Sita Trust only allow<br />

applicants to apply for<br />

funds for the same site or<br />

project once in any three<br />

year period<br />

This varies according to<br />

which DEB is applied to –<br />

there is usually a distance<br />

limitation with which the<br />

project must comply, e.g. 3<br />

miles with an active landfill<br />

ENTRUST are an<br />

independent regulatory<br />

body. Funding is<br />

distributed through<br />

Distributive Environmental<br />

Bodies who make the<br />

decision regarding the<br />

funding.<br />

Registered Environmental<br />

Bodies (EB) only can apply<br />

to the Fund. They must be<br />

a registered non-pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

organization.<br />

Due to the way in which<br />

landfill operators<br />

contribute to the fund they<br />

usually request around<br />

10% <strong>of</strong> the total funds to<br />

be sourced from a third<br />

party.<br />

The LCF is contributed to by landfill operators. They can contribute up to 6% <strong>of</strong> their<br />

landfill tax liability and then reclaim 90% <strong>of</strong> this contribution as a tax credit. 1122 The<br />

1122 Entrust (2009) Website Available: http://www.entrust.org.uk/home/lcf


additional 10% must be met by another funder to make the donation ‘cost-neutral’ to<br />

the landfill operator.<br />

The The The UK UK UK Aggregates Aggregates Aggregates Levy Levy Levy Sustainability Sustainability Sustainability Fund Fund Fund (ALSF) (ALSF)<br />

(ALSF)<br />

The UK aggregates levy provides the source <strong>of</strong> finance for the Aggregates Levy<br />

Sustainability Fund (ALSF). The aggregates levy is an environmental tax on the<br />

commercial exploitation <strong>of</strong> primary aggregate in the UK. The total fund is in the region<br />

<strong>of</strong> £15 million per year. The Aggregates Levy is set at £1.60 per tonne, with the<br />

exception <strong>of</strong> those in Northern Ireland who only pay 20% <strong>of</strong> the levy which equates to<br />

£0.32 per tonne in return for committing to making significant environmental<br />

improvements.<br />

Western Western Australia’s Australia’s <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Avoidance Avoidance and and Resource Resource Recovery Recovery Account<br />

Account<br />

Western Australia’s landfill levy finances a range <strong>of</strong> zero-waste related schemes. The<br />

fund is financed through direct allocation <strong>of</strong> all funds collected through the levy. The<br />

levy is currently set at $8/tonne and is paid by landfill operators located in, or<br />

receiving waste from, the Perth metropolitan area. The fund is worth just under $20<br />

million/year. In a ‘Landfill Levy <strong>Review</strong>’ undertaken for the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board<br />

<strong>of</strong> Western Australia it is reported that the levy itself was imposed in order to generate<br />

revenue to fund projects which were focused on resource recovery and reducing<br />

waste to landfill:<br />

913<br />

“As reported by ECS (2003), the 1995 Report <strong>of</strong> the Parliamentary Select<br />

Committee on Recycling and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> stated that the levy concept<br />

was developed primarily to fund a range <strong>of</strong> activities related to waste<br />

minimisation and recycling. The levy rate was determined by dividing the total<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> funds needed by the estimated tonnage to landfill.” 1123<br />

This might appear a somewhat unusual approach to take to the introduction <strong>of</strong> a levy,<br />

though in reality, one objective <strong>of</strong> levies is likely to be to raise revenue, whatever the<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> the destination <strong>of</strong> the funds so raised. However, due to the increasing levy<br />

rate the focus <strong>of</strong> this policy has now changed, with more emphasis placed on<br />

capturing externalities and directly influencing waste management.<br />

60.4.2 Centralised Public Finance<br />

Money that has been allocated from a centralised budget to be used as funding is<br />

less predictable and far more variable in size than those derived from taxation, as<br />

exemplified by the following examples:<br />

The The European European Commission<br />

Commission<br />

The European Commission run a series <strong>of</strong> funds which are sourced from public<br />

money. The Directorate General for the Environment makes runs three funding<br />

programmes which could be relevant to waste-related projects: the LIFE fund, the<br />

Competitiveness and Innovation Programme – Entrepreneurship and Innovation<br />

1123 Four Scenes Pty Ltd (2007) Landfill Levy <strong>Review</strong>, Report to the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board <strong>of</strong><br />

Western Australia, Available: http://www.zerowastewa.com.au/documents/landfill_levy_51107.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Programme (CIP-EIP) and through grants to environmental NGOs. In 2008 their CIP-<br />

EIP fund was worth £28 million for which they received 444 submissions from 32<br />

countries. 1124<br />

WRAP WRAP Construction Construction <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Recycling Support Support Programme<br />

Programme<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> and Resources Action Programme (WRAP) launched a capital grant fund in<br />

2006 in England (the Construction <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Infrastructure Capital Support<br />

Programme), followed by a similar stream <strong>of</strong> funding in Scotland in 2008 (the WRAP<br />

Construction and Demolition Capital Grant Programme for Scotland) and Wales (the<br />

Materials Action Programme Wales Capital Grant Programme). WRAP is a not-forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

company who are backed by government funding from England, Scotland,<br />

Wales and Northern Ireland.<br />

A WRAP report from 2007 suggests that the total amount <strong>of</strong> funding made available<br />

to support C&D waste infrastructure up to 2007 was £9.3 million. 1125 If bidders are<br />

successful, the programme will provide up to 30% <strong>of</strong> their eligible capital costs.<br />

These construction recycling funding streams are part <strong>of</strong> the WRAP Capital Grant<br />

Programme which aims to fund areas <strong>of</strong> strategic need or focus upon areas where<br />

market failures have been identified. It is worth noting that the source <strong>of</strong> the finance<br />

for the capital grants varies, depending upon the funding stream. For example, the<br />

WRAP aggregates program, is financed through the ALSF, described in Section<br />

60.4.1. In the 2009/10 financial year WRAP aims to fund food waste reprocessing<br />

facilities with a total capacity <strong>of</strong> 550,000 tonnes a year from a total fund <strong>of</strong> £14<br />

million.<br />

WRAP WRAP Organic Organics Organic Capital Grant Grant Programme Programme<br />

WRAP’s organic capital grant programme aims to provide funding towards the<br />

development <strong>of</strong> ABPR-compliant, thermophilic aerobic digestion or anaerobic<br />

digestion facilities. It was launched in 2008 and was eligible to applicants in England,<br />

Scotland and Northern Ireland. Projects must be able to demonstrate diversion <strong>of</strong><br />

organic waste from landfill in order to produce recycled products. The funding,<br />

similarly to their other capital grant schemes, funds up to 30% <strong>of</strong> the capital set-up<br />

costs.<br />

Defra Defra Anaerobic Anaerobic Digestion Digestion Demonstration Demonstration Programme Programme<br />

Programme<br />

This £10 million fund aims to demonstrate the benefits <strong>of</strong> anaerobic digestion to a<br />

range <strong>of</strong> industries. The fund is being administered by WRAP and the Carbon Trust.<br />

Californian Californian Construction Construction and and Demolition Demolition <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

In the USA funding for construction and demolition materials management projects is<br />

most typically provided from the State level, e.g. the California Integrated <strong>Waste</strong><br />

1124 European Commission (2008) A Wealth <strong>of</strong> Ideas for a Greener Europe, Available:<br />

http://ec.europa.eu/environment/eco-innovation/docs/publi/brochure_en_09.pdf<br />

1125 WRAP (2006) WRAP Completes £2.3 M <strong>of</strong> Funding for Aggregate Recyclers, Available:<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/wrap_corporate/news/wrap_completes_23m.html<br />

914<br />

29/09/09


<strong>Management</strong> Board (CIWMB) provide grants which are funded by the Californian<br />

State Government. Funding is also made available at the Federal level, although far<br />

less frequently. This is through the Environmental Protection Agency’s Office <strong>of</strong> Solid<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> and Emergency Response (OSWER). 1126 Information on the total funds<br />

available over any time period could not be found.<br />

Prevention Prevention Stimulating Stimulating Programme Programme ( (PREST ( PREST PRESTI) PREST )<br />

The Government <strong>of</strong> Flanders’ PRESTI programme began in 1994. Since then a series<br />

<strong>of</strong> PRESTI programmes have been run which have had the following OVAM (Public<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Agency <strong>of</strong> Flanders) budget:<br />

915<br />

� PRESTI 1 (1994-1997): 3,200,000 Euro<br />

� PRESTI 2 (1997-2001): 560,000 Euro<br />

� PRESTI 3 (1997-2002): 407,000 Euro<br />

� PRESTI 4 (1998-2004): 1,622,000 Euro<br />

� PRESTI 5 (2003-2008): 2,980,000 Euro<br />

60.5 Objectives <strong>of</strong> Fund<br />

The main reason for public sector intervention is to manage market failures, in<br />

particular to internalise production/consumption externalities which may result from<br />

imperfect competition within a market. This means working towards effectively<br />

reflecting the true price <strong>of</strong> a good or service in the cost through government<br />

intervention which should result in a more efficient allocation <strong>of</strong> resources. 1127 Ins<strong>of</strong>ar<br />

as this is the case, then where waste management is concerned, in principle,<br />

internalising externalities and implementing rational policies ought, in well-functioning<br />

markets, to enable the market to deliver the desired outcomes. In practice, markets<br />

do not always operate efficiently, and capital grants might be especially appropriate<br />

as means to stimulate investment in times when the terms upon which companies<br />

can access credit are somewhat poor, as at the time <strong>of</strong> writing.<br />

60.5.1 Environmental Taxation<br />

Environmental taxes are predominantly conceived as measures to ensure that the<br />

environmental cost <strong>of</strong> an environmentally damaging procedure is reflected in the<br />

price, though the reality remains that this is rarely the basis for setting the level <strong>of</strong><br />

such taxes. Revenue is occasionally ear-marked and an environmental fund is set-up.<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> the fund is to finance projects which work to <strong>of</strong>fset the environmental or<br />

social damage, or change behaviour, to reduce reliance on the environmentally<br />

damaging service or product. Two UK based examples follow:<br />

1126 United States Environmental Protection Agency (website) Available:<br />

http://www.epa.gov/osw/conserve/rrr/imr/cdm/grants.htm<br />

1127 European Commission DG for Regional <strong>Policy</strong> Evaluation Unit (2006) Cost-Benefit Analysis and EU<br />

Regional <strong>Policy</strong> Main Lessons from the Experience, Draft paper prepared for the 5 th Milan European<br />

Economy workshop 26-27 May 2006, Available:<br />

http://florio.economia.unimi.it/Materiali/MEEW5/Mairate.doc<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The The The Landfill Landfill Landfill Communities Communities Communities Fund Fund<br />

Fund<br />

The Landfill Communities Fund (LCF) was set up to help mitigate the effects <strong>of</strong> landfill<br />

upon those living within a close proximity to the site. The LCF was formerly the Landfill<br />

Tax Credit Scheme which had a much wider remit and covered waste research<br />

projects, although they had to be within a certain proximity <strong>of</strong> the site. The fund has<br />

the following specific objectives:<br />

916<br />

1. The remediation <strong>of</strong> land (Object A)<br />

2. The prevention <strong>of</strong> pollution (Object B)<br />

3. The reduction <strong>of</strong> waste (Object C)<br />

4. The recycling <strong>of</strong> waste (Object CC)<br />

5. Public parks and public amenities (Object D)<br />

6. Biodiversity conservation (Object DA)<br />

7. The restoration <strong>of</strong> places <strong>of</strong> worship and historic buildings (Object E)<br />

8. The provision <strong>of</strong> services to other Environmental Bodies (Object F)<br />

The The The Aggregates Aggregates Aggregates Levy Levy Levy Sustainability Sustainability Sustainability Fund Fund<br />

Fund<br />

Similarly to the LCF, the ALSF’s overall main aim is to:<br />

29/09/09<br />

“reduce the environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> the extraction <strong>of</strong> aggregates and to<br />

deliver benefits to areas subject to these impacts”. 1128<br />

It aims to achieve this through the following objectives:<br />

1. Quarries - To reduce the environmental footprint <strong>of</strong> quarries and to take<br />

advantage <strong>of</strong> the opportunities they <strong>of</strong>fer.<br />

2. Marine - To reduce the environmental footprint <strong>of</strong> marine extraction.<br />

3. Resource Use - To deliver more sustainable use <strong>of</strong> aggregates.<br />

4. Transport - To reduce the environmental footprint <strong>of</strong> the transport <strong>of</strong><br />

aggregates.<br />

5. Communities - To deliver benefits to communities affected by extraction. 1129<br />

60.5.2 Centralised Public Finance<br />

Grant funding that is provided through a government’s central budget is<br />

disassociated with one product or service, in the way that funds sourced from<br />

environmental taxes are. Therefore, a need must be identified for the fund to be put<br />

1128 Defra (2009) Website: Aggregates Levy Sustainability Fund in England, Available:<br />

http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/waste/aggregates/index.htm<br />

1129 Defra (2009) Website: Aggregates Levy Sustainability Fund in England, Available:<br />

http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/waste/aggregates/index.htm


in place. This is very <strong>of</strong>ten to enable the government to reach targets or goals. The<br />

variety <strong>of</strong> these funding streams are shown by the following examples:<br />

Eco Eco-Innovation Eco Eco Innovation Innovation Fund Fund<br />

The European Commission runs an Eco-Innovation fund, which seeks to further,<br />

917<br />

“All forms <strong>of</strong> innovation which reduce environmental impacts and/or<br />

optimising the use <strong>of</strong> resources”.<br />

Construction Construction <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Recycling Infrastructure Infrastructure Capital Capital Support Support Programme<br />

Programme<br />

WRAP’s Construction <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling Infrastructure Capital Support Programme aims<br />

to boost capacity for recycling construction waste. It specifically focuses on the noninert<br />

fractions <strong>of</strong> construction and demolition waste and aims to stimulate ‘step<br />

change in the collection, segregation, recovery and recycling rates <strong>of</strong> materials’. 1130<br />

Defra Defra Anaerobic Anaerobic Digestion Demonstration Programme<br />

The five key aims <strong>of</strong> this programme are:<br />

� Maximising the cost effective production <strong>of</strong> biogas;<br />

� Maximising the environmental benefits from the use <strong>of</strong> anaerobic digestions<br />

and its products;<br />

� Maximising the potential <strong>of</strong> anaerobic digestion to reduce the carbon footprint<br />

<strong>of</strong> the food supply chain;<br />

� Maximising the opportunity for the injection <strong>of</strong> biomethane into the gas grid;<br />

and<br />

� Maximising the potential <strong>of</strong> anaerobic digestion to reduce the carbon footprint<br />

<strong>of</strong> water treatment infrastructure.<br />

Californian Californian Californian Construction Construction and and Demolition Demolition <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong><br />

The CIWMB provides the Californian public and private sector with grants in order to<br />

enable the State’s waste reduction, reuse and recycling targets to be achieved. There<br />

are 11 main grant programs, <strong>of</strong> which the Sustainable Building Grant program is <strong>of</strong><br />

most relevance to the construction sector and the Deconstruction Grant Programme<br />

which only ran for 1 year in 1999.<br />

Californian Californian Environmental Environmental Protection Protection Agency Agency (EPA)<br />

(EPA)<br />

The Californian EPA has provided grants under their Innovations Initiative which aims<br />

to fund work with a greater emphasis on research. They have funded innovative pilot<br />

projects which focus on development <strong>of</strong> new approaches towards waste minimisation,<br />

energy recovery and recycling.<br />

1130 WRAP (2006) WRAP Targets C&D <strong>Waste</strong> with New Capital Funding Competition, Available:<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/wrap_corporate/news/wrap_targets_cd.html<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Strategic Strategic Strategic <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Initiatives Initiatives Initiatives Scheme Scheme<br />

Scheme<br />

The Western Australian <strong>Waste</strong> Authority runs two streams <strong>of</strong> grant schemes: the<br />

Strategic <strong>Waste</strong> Initiatives Scheme and the Community Grants Scheme. Of most<br />

relevance to the waste sector is the Strategic <strong>Waste</strong> Initiatives Scheme which has<br />

identified five priority areas:<br />

918<br />

29/09/09<br />

1. Green <strong>Waste</strong>;<br />

2. Construction and Demolition;<br />

3. Plastics;<br />

4. Used Tyres; and<br />

5. Hazardous <strong>Waste</strong> from Households.<br />

Proposals must be submitted for initiatives must be relevant to one <strong>of</strong> the five priority<br />

areas and consistent with the ‘Statement <strong>of</strong> Strategic Direction for <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> in Western Australia’.<br />

Prevention Prevention Prevention Stimulating Stimulating Stimulating Programme Programme Programme ( (PRESTI ( ( PRESTI PRESTI)<br />

)<br />

The main over-arching objective <strong>of</strong> the PRESTI programme was to stimulate SME’s to<br />

integrate environmental management and prevention in their policy. However, each <strong>of</strong><br />

the five PRESTI programmes have differed from one another:<br />

PRESTI 1 <strong>of</strong>fered practical and usable information to a group <strong>of</strong> enterprises in the<br />

same activity-sector through using federations as partners. PRESTI 1 also wanted<br />

increase ongoing prevention awareness in federations, that remained ingrained after<br />

the ending <strong>of</strong> PRESTI 1.<br />

PRESTI 2 gave financial support to federations for demonstration projects, a step<br />

further than PRESTI 1. Pilot enterprises were screened and some prevention<br />

measures were executed.<br />

PRESTI 3 <strong>of</strong>fered support to individual SME’s. Participating SME’s developed a<br />

prevention plan. In a second phase, this plan was implemented where possible.<br />

PRESTI 4 supported intermediary organisations developing systems to promote<br />

prevention and environmental management in enterprises. PRESTI 4 was available to<br />

each Flemish province.<br />

PRESTI 5 supported research, demonstration projects and pilot projects. Research<br />

and education institutions, environmental and socio-cultural associations, as well as<br />

businesses were eligible for this fund.<br />

60.6 Period <strong>of</strong> Operation<br />

60.6.1 Environmental Taxation<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> funds which are financed through taxation, such as the LCF and the<br />

ALSF, have been ongoing since the launch <strong>of</strong> the fund shortly after the launch <strong>of</strong> the<br />

tax, in 1997 and 2002, respectively. This type <strong>of</strong> fund is predictable and politically<br />

popular because a direct association between the revenue and the benefit provide<br />

reasoning for implementation <strong>of</strong> the tax.


However, earmarking reduces flexibility in public finances so ought to be withdrawn<br />

when the funds objectives have been met. 1131 Equally, if levies increase, and if, as a<br />

result <strong>of</strong> inelastic responses, the total revenue generated increases, questions should<br />

be asked as to whether the size <strong>of</strong> the fund might simply generate waste in the use <strong>of</strong><br />

revenues. Although there are no examples <strong>of</strong> the fund actually being withdrawn, the<br />

following evidence shows examples <strong>of</strong> continuous evaluation.<br />

Taking the case <strong>of</strong> the landfill tax in the UK, this was introduced in order to reduce the<br />

reliance upon landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste. Despite being ongoing since 1997, the fund did<br />

change from the Landfill tax Credit Scheme to the Landfill Community Fund and in<br />

doing so the objectives <strong>of</strong> the fund were shifted to a greater focus on communities<br />

affected by landfills sites. This shift shows that evaluation <strong>of</strong> the fund was taking<br />

place and potentially old objectives were deemed either unnecessary or they had<br />

been met.<br />

A similar example <strong>of</strong> good practice occurred in Western Australia when their <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> and Recycling Fund (WMRF) (funded by the landfill levy) was suspended<br />

in 2002 whilst a review was undertaken. Following this, the focus <strong>of</strong> the funding<br />

strongly shifted to a zero waste focus and a series <strong>of</strong> Zero <strong>Waste</strong> Schemes were<br />

introduced under the new Strategic <strong>Waste</strong> Initiatives Schemes, in 2004. 1132 It was felt<br />

that although there was some merit to the previous funding expenditures, they lacked<br />

innovation and leadership.<br />

The ALSF was introduced in 2002 as a two-year pilot scheme which has been<br />

extended by between 1 and 3 years ever since, currently up until 2011. This has been<br />

through a series <strong>of</strong> reviews and consultations. There are no definitive indications at<br />

this stage as to whether or not it will be renewed yet again, but it seems likely that<br />

this will occur.<br />

60.6.2 Centralised Public Finance<br />

In contrast to funding sourced from taxation, centrally financed public grants tend to<br />

be available for a limited period <strong>of</strong> time and with specific objectives in mind. Each<br />

programme has a specific launch date and deadline date for application and date<br />

marking the end <strong>of</strong> the availability <strong>of</strong> the fund.<br />

For example, WRAP’s capital funding stream which focused on increasing<br />

plasterboard recycling was launched in February 2007 and applications had to be<br />

received by 30 th April 2007. Projects receiving the funding had to be operational by<br />

the following March.<br />

1131 OECD (2007) <strong>Policy</strong> Brief: Making Environmental Spending Count, Available:<br />

http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/1/18/39376495.pdf<br />

1132 Western Australia <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environment and Conservation (2009) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>,<br />

Website available:<br />

http://portal.environment.wa.gov.au/portal/page?_pageid=53,34379&_dad=portal&_schema=PORTA<br />

L<br />

919<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


60.7 Decision/Allocation Mechanism for Funding Awards<br />

The most <strong>of</strong>t-cited method to allocate funding is through a competitive tendering<br />

process. The way in which this is administered varies across funding streams.<br />

However, it is common for environmental funds, financed by the taxation, to be set up<br />

in order to administer and manage the allocation <strong>of</strong> the money. The way in which this<br />

fund is managed varies greatly as demonstrated by the following examples.<br />

The LCF is regulated by the independent organisation ENTRUST. They are not-forpr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

and non-governmental. Although not involved in the final allocation <strong>of</strong> the fund,<br />

Entrust are fundamental to reviewing the projects undertaken by environmental<br />

bodies. Distributive Environmental Bodies makes the decision regarding the project<br />

funding – these are <strong>of</strong>ten associated with the Landfill Operator, e.g. SITA Trust, Viridor<br />

Credits Environmental Company. The taxes which are not donated to the fund<br />

managed by HM Treasury, who also oversee ENTRUST, and DEFRA is instrumental in<br />

setting out the goals which the fund hopes to achieve. Despite the ongoing nature <strong>of</strong><br />

the funding applicants can only apply for the same site or project once every three<br />

years. 1133<br />

The ALSF is managed by the following governments and government departments:<br />

Defra in England; the Welsh Assembly Government in Wales; the Scottish Government<br />

in Scotland; and the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment in Northern Ireland. In England,<br />

the management bodies set the overall fund objectives and then allocate funding to<br />

delivering partners who then receive applications for the fund. There are nine national<br />

organisations and 18 local authorities (who have the highest level <strong>of</strong> aggregates<br />

production) who are delivery partners.<br />

A competitive tendering process, managed by the Capital Grants Team at WRAP, is<br />

undertaken to allocate the funding to the most relevant project proposals. This<br />

includes having the applications independently assessed by a financial or<br />

environmental assessor and specialist panel. From the announcement <strong>of</strong> the<br />

availability <strong>of</strong> the fund there is approximately 10 weeks until the deadline for<br />

applications. A requirement <strong>of</strong> the grant scheme is that the outcome <strong>of</strong> the funding<br />

must be operational in 2 years from the application deadline. In order to support the<br />

application process WRAP ran free workshop events.<br />

European Structural and Cohesion funds are allocated as a result <strong>of</strong> a Cost-Benefit<br />

Analysis (CBA). CBA is used as an evaluation tool to ensure that the fund gets<br />

distributed to projects which are value for money in terms <strong>of</strong> effectiveness and<br />

efficiency in contributing towards the main goals <strong>of</strong> the EU funds. CBA also assesses<br />

the extent to which the project needs the grant, and the level <strong>of</strong> funding required,<br />

using the ‘funding-gap’ method. 1134 The European Commission has encouraged this<br />

assessment methodology across Member States.<br />

1133 Sita Trust, Enriching Nature Guidance Notes, Available:<br />

http://preview.sitatrust.org.uk/resources/documents/DA/DA_Guidance_Notes10.09.08.doc.dot<br />

1134 European Commission DG for Regional <strong>Policy</strong> Evaluation Unit (2006) Cost-Benefit Analysis and EU<br />

Regional <strong>Policy</strong> Main Lessons from the Experience, Draft paper prepared for the 5 th Milan European<br />

920<br />

29/09/09


60.8 Approach to Evaluating Effects <strong>of</strong> Environmental Funds<br />

In 1995, the OECD developed the ‘St. Petersburg Guidelines for Environmental Funds<br />

in the Transition to a Market Economy’ which have provided a benchmark by which to<br />

evaluate environmental funds. The main conclusions <strong>of</strong> the Guidelines include those<br />

set out in the Box below: 1135<br />

Effective evaluation <strong>of</strong> an environmental fund is necessary because it provides<br />

information on whether the fund’s objectives are being successfully achieved and in<br />

light <strong>of</strong> this whether or not the fund should be continued. 1136<br />

This is particularly important for ear-marked funds because they can lead to<br />

inefficient distribution <strong>of</strong> funding if areas outside the ear-marked sector are in greater<br />

need <strong>of</strong> the funding. This point was discussed in Section 60.6, in terms <strong>of</strong> how long<br />

funds operate for, and the ongoing evaluation that is required.<br />

Acquiring information that covers any greater level <strong>of</strong> detailed evaluation, other than<br />

that described in Section 60.8, has proven challenging. It seems that there is a<br />

distinct lack <strong>of</strong> available information regarding funding evaluation. Any available<br />

information is published by an associated organisation, rather than an independent<br />

reviewer.<br />

For example, WRAP explicitly state their targets for the aggregate programme, which<br />

was funded through the ALSF. The fund was to achieve the following by 2006:<br />

921<br />

1. To deliver a 3 million tonne increase in reprocessing capacity for recycled and<br />

secondary aggregates.<br />

2. To bring about a 10% increase in the use <strong>of</strong> recycled and secondary<br />

aggregates in higher-value (non-fill) applications.<br />

3. To develop, agree and communicate quality protocols for the specification and<br />

point <strong>of</strong> recovery <strong>of</strong> recycled and secondary aggregates.<br />

4. To promote and facilitate the specification <strong>of</strong> recycled and secondary<br />

aggregates to the point where 10% <strong>of</strong> local authorities are specifying these<br />

materials in street maintenance contracts by 2005, rising to 20% by 2006.<br />

5. To deliver a minimum <strong>of</strong> 50 training opportunities during the course <strong>of</strong> the<br />

programme supported by new tools and information within the aggregates<br />

supply chain.<br />

Economy workshop 26-27 May 2006, Available:<br />

http://florio.economia.unimi.it/Materiali/MEEW5/Mairate.doc<br />

1135 Speck S., J. McNicholas and M. Markovic (eds) (2001) Environmental Funds in the Candidate<br />

Countries, The Regional Environmental Center for Central and Eastern Europe, Szentendre, Hungary<br />

based on OECD (1995) Environmental Funds in Economies in Transition, Paris<br />

1136 OECD (2006) Recommendation <strong>of</strong> the Council on Good Practices for Public Environmental<br />

Expenditure <strong>Management</strong>, Available: http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/10/46/38787377.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


922<br />

Box Box 11:<br />

1 1:<br />

: St St Petersburg Petersburg Guidelines Guidelines on on Environmental Environmental Funds<br />

Funds<br />

� To avoid or minimize the long-term economic inefficiencies inherent in the<br />

earmarking <strong>of</strong> funds, expenditure should be targeted to meet environmental<br />

priorities and promote projects with large environmental benefits relative to their<br />

costs.<br />

� Environmental funds should play a catalytic role in financing, ideally <strong>of</strong>fering no<br />

more support for project than is necessary, adapt to changing economic<br />

conditions, and support, not compete with, emerging capital markets.<br />

� Environmental funds should be used in conjunction with, and reinforce, other<br />

environmental policy instruments, such as compliance schedules,<br />

environmental auditing programs and voluntary agreements.<br />

� Environmental Environmental funds funds should should develop develop an an overall overall financing financing strategy, strategy, follow follow follow clear<br />

clear<br />

and and explicit explicit operating operating procedures procedures for for evaluating evaluating and and selecting selecting projects, projects, adopt<br />

adopt<br />

effective effective monitoring monitoring and and evaluation evaluation practices, practices, and and make m<br />

ake effective use <strong>of</strong><br />

internal internal internal and and and external external external expertise expertise expertise to to to enhance enhance enhance administrative administrative administrative efficiency. efficiency.<br />

efficiency.<br />

� For For For investment investment projects, projects, funds funds should should have have have well well-designed well well designed program program and and project project<br />

project<br />

cycles cycles to to ensure ensure cost cost-effective cost effective use <strong>of</strong> resources.<br />

� Environmental Environmental funds funds should should leverage leverage iincreased<br />

i increased<br />

ncreased private private private sector resources resources and<br />

capital capital market market financing financing for for environmental environmental investments.<br />

investments.<br />

� In defining and evaluating fund revenue mechanisms, environmental<br />

authorities should try to ensure environmental effectiveness, economic and<br />

administrative efficiency, equity and acceptability. Systems should provide a<br />

stable base <strong>of</strong> revenues, be simple in structure, and be easy to monitor and<br />

enforce.<br />

� Environmental funds should ensure transparency and should be accountable<br />

to government, parliaments, and the public for their actions.<br />

Source: Eunomia & University <strong>of</strong> Pretoria (2003) Fiscal Reform in South Africa, A Final Report for<br />

National Treasury <strong>of</strong> South Africa.<br />

In Defra’s report, ‘Aggregates Levy Sustainability Fund in England 2002-2007’ these<br />

targets are reported but the outcome <strong>of</strong> each is not. Each <strong>of</strong> the five aforementioned<br />

targets are measurable in some way – however this is not demonstrated. The case is<br />

same for other WRAP funding streams – where the funding targets are clearly<br />

identifiable but the outcome is not.<br />

WRAP’s Capital Grant Team were contacted but felt they were unable to answer<br />

questions regarding how the capital funding streams were evaluated without<br />

breaching confidentiality <strong>of</strong> those who received the fund. Their website provides no<br />

substantial information on how this process is undertaken.<br />

Individual case studies are readily available, which suggests that information over the<br />

fund could, and probably has been collated. However, accessing this information is<br />

problematic.<br />

29/09/09


There is evidence to suggest that environmental funds have been developed in-line<br />

with the St. Petersburg Guidelines, therefore they have the intention <strong>of</strong> following best<br />

practise. For example, Sita, on behalf <strong>of</strong> the LCF, include the following in their<br />

Guidance Notes:<br />

“Projects should be self-sustaining once the initial project funding has been<br />

invested. This will include ensuring that the project can be managed and<br />

maintained and that funding is available to cover these costs into the<br />

future.” 1137<br />

The problem lies in post-evaluation <strong>of</strong> the fund, where although user-friendly casestudies<br />

are frequently available to show project specific outcomes <strong>of</strong> the funding,<br />

data to analyse overall fund efficiencies is not widely released. That is not to say that<br />

detailed evaluation <strong>of</strong> the fund does not take place, because it most certainly does,<br />

but the results <strong>of</strong> which are not widely circulated.<br />

60.9 Environmental Impact <strong>of</strong> Fund<br />

The OECD’s 2006 ‘Recommendation <strong>of</strong> the Council on Good Practices for Public<br />

Environmental Expenditure <strong>Management</strong>’ provides a good practice checklist for<br />

establishing, reviewing and reforming public environmental funding programmes in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> environmental effectiveness. It is structured using 5 principles, under which<br />

good practices are provided, a summary <strong>of</strong> which is below:<br />

Principle 1: Additionality and consistency with other environmental policy instruments<br />

Good Practices: the need for the fund should be justified through the polluter-pays<br />

/user pays principle. 1138 They should not be used to reach objectives which should<br />

have been reached via a policy mechanism, or to fund projects which could have<br />

received private investment. The fund should compliment existing policies. It should<br />

be used to finance capital costs, not operational. The fund should be regularly<br />

audited, and phased out when their role is fulfilled.<br />

Principle 2: Well-defined programming framework<br />

The fund should be distributed via a publicly-available expenditure programme which<br />

is set within a wider policy-setting, and which has been approved by the appropriate<br />

bodies.<br />

Principle 3: Clear identification <strong>of</strong> environmental outcomes<br />

Quantitative and qualitative information on projects’ environmental outcomes should<br />

be submitted in a standard format, and expressed in monetary format where possible<br />

to allow cost-benefit analysis to be undertaken. Environmental outcomes should be<br />

1137 Sita Trust, Enhancing Communities Large Grants Scheme Guidance Notes, Available:<br />

http://www.sitatrust.org.uk/resources/documents/LGS/LGS_Guidance_Notes3mile11.03.09.pdf<br />

1138 The Polluter-Pays-Principle (PPP) requires polluters to pay the full costs <strong>of</strong> any subsequent clean-up<br />

without subsidies. The User-Pays-Principle states that revenue generated by users must cover all the<br />

costs related to the use <strong>of</strong> a natural resource.<br />

923<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


monitored during and after the project. The funding body should take action if<br />

expected outcomes were not achieved. Finally, information<br />

Principle 4: Maximise environmental effect from available funds<br />

Quantitative and qualitative information on projects’ costs should be submitted in a<br />

standard format in order to allow verification, analysis and indicate costeffectiveness.<br />

Principle 5: Leverage additional finance<br />

Public funds should not fund 100% project costs and the percentage <strong>of</strong> project costs<br />

borrowed, or financial leverage, should be used to assess the programme’s<br />

performance. Public funding should not distort competition in the market.<br />

Quantifying the overall environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> a fund is very difficult because<br />

although case studies are usually available they are very succinct. The following<br />

examples aim to give an overview <strong>of</strong> the environmental impacts.<br />

WRAP WRAP WRAP Aggregate Aggregate Capital Capital Grant Grant Support Support<br />

In 2007 a WRAP report suggested that the capital investment they had provided so<br />

far had resulted in the addition <strong>of</strong> more than 3.6 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> annual recycling<br />

capacity. As well as this significant increase in capacity the focus has been on<br />

increasing the production <strong>of</strong> high quality recycled aggregate<br />

With the announcement <strong>of</strong> the fund in Scotland and Wales being in 2008 the projects<br />

will not yet have been completed. However, the fund’s environmental impact in<br />

England can be illustrated via the following short case study produced by WRAP:<br />

924<br />

29/09/09<br />

� Eppleton Quarry Products Ltd received £101,000 for mobile plant for the<br />

extraction <strong>of</strong> secondary aggregates from slag. This resulted in an increased<br />

capacity which rose from 125,000 tonnes to 505,000 <strong>of</strong> quality recycled<br />

aggregate. The environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> this are two-fold: as a direct<br />

result <strong>of</strong> the project a greater quantity <strong>of</strong> waste is diverted away from<br />

landfill in order to be recycled into quality aggregate material; and there is<br />

potential for this to reduce the demand for virgin aggregate. The extraction<br />

process can create noise, it’s unsightly and requires transportation from<br />

the quarry to the site.. 1139<br />

Aggregates ggregates Levy evy Sustainability<br />

ustainability Fund und<br />

A summary report <strong>of</strong> the ALSF in its first four years, since 2002, was published by<br />

Defra. The main environmental achievements were:<br />

� funding equipment with the capacity to recycle 1.7 million tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

construction and demolition waste or process secondary aggregate;<br />

� making improvements at or around existing or disused quarries; and<br />

1139 WRAP Applying for a WRAP Capital Grant?, Available:<br />

http://www.wrap.org.uk/businesses/business_and_markets/capital_grants.html


925<br />

� undertaking research on quarry restoration, sustainable construction<br />

and demolition processes and assessment and evaluation <strong>of</strong> wreck sites<br />

at sea.<br />

Californian Californian Californian Integrated Integrated <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Board Board<br />

Board<br />

The State and Consumer Services Agency received $250,000 in 2001 in order to<br />

construct streets with rubberised asphalt concrete (RAC), derived from tyres, into the<br />

East End Complex. This resulted in the diversion <strong>of</strong> approximately 11,000 waste tyres<br />

from stockpiles and landfills around California. 1140<br />

Californian Californian Californian Environmental<br />

nvironmental Protection rotection Agency gency<br />

The University <strong>of</strong> Florida, the City <strong>of</strong> Gainsville and Gainesville Regional Utilities<br />

partnered with the EPA in order to work on a deconstruction research project. The<br />

work involved deconstructing a typical Florida wooden-framed house and effectively<br />

utilising the constituent materials in new construction projects. Estimations<br />

suggested that if only 60% <strong>of</strong> materials were recovered this would result in diverting<br />

27 tons <strong>of</strong> waste from landfill. 1141<br />

Prevention Prevention Stimulating Stimulating Programme Programme ( (PRESTI ( PRESTI PRESTI) PRESTI )<br />

As by far the largest part <strong>of</strong> industrial waste in Flanders is generated by SMEs, they<br />

are a useful target group. SMEs usually lack the required knowledge and know-how to<br />

understand the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> waste prevention, and how it helps in saving raw<br />

materials and workload, and therefore they need to be supported by these external<br />

instruments to make progress in the field <strong>of</strong> waste prevention.<br />

The first PRESTI programme financed 32 projects and as a result, reached 15,262<br />

enterprises out <strong>of</strong> a total <strong>of</strong> 40,505 potentially reachable enterprises. The benefits <strong>of</strong><br />

the programme were a higher awareness and knowledge level on prevention.<br />

Research on the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the PRESTI 2-programme, showed that 2,000<br />

enterprises were positively affected by the programme. 13 projects were executed.<br />

PRESTI 3 supported 30 SME’s.<br />

More than 300 enterprises participated in the PRESTI 4 programme. Even though the<br />

PRESTI 4 programme ended, most provinces continue with the ‘Environmental<br />

Charter’ themselves, keeping the original logo.<br />

No evaluation is yet available for PRESTI 5.<br />

60.10 Costs <strong>of</strong> Administering Fund<br />

A variety <strong>of</strong> methods for administering the funds have been described but no<br />

information could be identified which gave an approximation <strong>of</strong> the administrative<br />

1140 CIWMB (2001) CIWMB Grants Database Reports, Available:<br />

http://www.ciwmb.ca.gov/Grants/Reports/ByCycle.asp<br />

1141 United States Environmental Protection Agency (2002) OSWER Innovations Pilot Building<br />

Deconstruction and Reuse, Available: http://www.epa.gov/oswer/docs/iwg/Deconstruction.pdf<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


costs involved. However, typically these are a small proportion <strong>of</strong> total funding<br />

awards, or at least, they should be. Having said that, as part <strong>of</strong> the administration, it<br />

is important to evaluate projects. This should be seen as an integral part <strong>of</strong> the fund’s<br />

administration.<br />

60.11 Advantages & Disadvantages <strong>of</strong> Environmental Taxation &<br />

Centralised Public Finance<br />

To have a fund/and or organisation which is set-up to <strong>of</strong>fset the impacts <strong>of</strong> an<br />

increase in environmental taxation is commonplace. It is a gesture which seeks to<br />

s<strong>of</strong>ten the impact <strong>of</strong> the tax increase to the private sector through directly<br />

demonstrating a positive impact the tax increase has had, e.g. the new fund or new<br />

organisation. This use <strong>of</strong> hypothecated resources can lead to a situation whereby<br />

money is allocated in a far less rigorous way than if it had come from central funds,<br />

where a far wider number <strong>of</strong> stakeholders would have to understand the value <strong>of</strong> the<br />

project in order to agree to allocating the money. It has been demonstrated (Section<br />

60.3) that within ongoing funds, and grant-funded organisations, money can be<br />

allocated to the same organisation repeatedly; it <strong>of</strong>ten has to be allocated within a<br />

particular timeframe; and the evaluation information widely available is from an<br />

internal source and therefore lacks independence. Although these are broadbrush<br />

generalisations it is fair to say these problems are much less likely to occur where<br />

money is being allocated from a central pot.<br />

There are further issues with setting up an organisation or a fund which is directly<br />

associated with an environmental tax. The likely justification for the establishment <strong>of</strong><br />

the organisation will be to combat the environmental problem which is being taxed, in<br />

order to change behaviour in some way. In theory, a sign that the fund has achieved<br />

its overall aim will be the reduction in available funding from the environmental tax,<br />

leading to reducing/ending the fund or downsizing/closing the organisation. However,<br />

as funds and organisations become established this becomes a very unlikely<br />

scenario. Unless the focus <strong>of</strong> the work funded continually evolves money could be<br />

being spent in highly inefficient ways due to a routine which has emerged.<br />

It is possible that alternative approaches, other than grant-funding, may be strongly<br />

supported by the private sector. For example, a ‘tax shift’ change, which has revenue<br />

neutral implications, uses an environmental tax as a mechanism to encourage a<br />

change in behaviour away from negative actions, whilst encouraging positive actions<br />

through a tax reduction elsewhere, e.g. income tax.<br />

This review has demonstrated the barriers which are commonly in place when trying<br />

to evaluate the funds and has identified some key positive aspects <strong>of</strong> grant funding.<br />

As such, it is felt that a key approach to ensuring the efficiency and effectiveness <strong>of</strong> a<br />

grant fund is measurability, and alongside this transparency. The overall aim <strong>of</strong> the<br />

fund must be clear. In order to know how close the fund is to meeting the overall aim<br />

the action taken must be measurable and strict guidance must be kept to in order to<br />

ensure continuity and accuracy <strong>of</strong> the measurement. This is fundamental to<br />

understanding the impact that the fund has, in order to then independently evaluate<br />

its success.<br />

926<br />

29/09/09


60.12 Lessons Learned<br />

The Flemish Prevention Stimulating Programme (PRESTI) highlights the following<br />

lessons learned:<br />

927<br />

� Surveys show a general raise in consciousness regarding waste costs and the<br />

environmental impact <strong>of</strong> products, particularly within industry.<br />

� The impact <strong>of</strong> the different awareness and education programmes and<br />

instruments is difficult to measure. Often no clear targets are set;<br />

� SMEs are a central target group because they <strong>of</strong>ten lack knowledge and knowhow<br />

and they are responsible for a large fraction <strong>of</strong> the industrial waste;<br />

� The effectiveness <strong>of</strong> the instruments largely depends upon their practical<br />

nature and the ease-<strong>of</strong>-use;<br />

� The largest motivating driving force for preventive actions is the saving <strong>of</strong><br />

costs, more than the environmental awareness; and<br />

� Strict monitoring and continuous improvement remains necessary to keep the<br />

instruments successful.<br />

Prerequisites for introduction <strong>of</strong> PRESTI are considered to be:<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> prevention should be embedded in the legislation;<br />

� Good monitoring structures are required;<br />

� A strong administrative backbone should support the instruments; and<br />

� Support from the industry intermediates is necessary.<br />

Rather few good examples <strong>of</strong> evaluations <strong>of</strong> other award programmes could be found.<br />

60.13 Concluding Comments<br />

The weaknesses <strong>of</strong> grant funding streams tend to be as follows:<br />

� Frequently, grants are awarded hastily and without sufficient consideration <strong>of</strong><br />

the time required to prepare quality bidding documents and to allow for the<br />

support to have its effect. This can result in low quality bids being prepared;<br />

� Awarding bodies rarely hold on to their money. Awards making bodies are<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten under pressure to disburse the whole pot <strong>of</strong> money. However, in our<br />

experience, it would <strong>of</strong>ten be better for award making bodies to hold on to<br />

their money where bids / applications are <strong>of</strong> low quality. Such bids rarely result<br />

in quality projects. The corollary <strong>of</strong> this is that award making bodies should not<br />

be under pressure to disburse money at all costs. Rather, care should be<br />

taken to structure the process such that the chances <strong>of</strong> receiving quality bids<br />

are maximised;<br />

� In line with what is suggested in the OECD Principles, insufficient additionality<br />

is obtained for the spend. In other words, the projects funded may have gone<br />

ahead anyway, or could have done so without grant funding;<br />

� Grant funding is sometimes used for projects which should not be supported<br />

by grants. This may even place a break on policy development if it implies that<br />

the polluter pays principle is not respected;<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


928<br />

� Rules regarding the split between capital and revenue spends are <strong>of</strong>ten rigidly<br />

applied;<br />

� Rules regarding the timing <strong>of</strong> spend are <strong>of</strong>ten unrealistic and put bidders <strong>of</strong>f;<br />

� In the case <strong>of</strong> hypothecated, or ear-marked revenue streams, there may be a<br />

tendency to engender inefficiency in the projects sponsored. This is<br />

particularly the case where projects become ‘favoured’ under a fund;<br />

� In the case <strong>of</strong> projects supported by hypothecated tax revenues, care has to<br />

be taken, when tax revenues increase, to ensure that funds do not simply<br />

support ‘more <strong>of</strong> the same’. This can lead to funds being wasted through<br />

duplication and inefficiency;<br />

� It probably makes sense to ensure that grant awarding bodies who are seeking<br />

to support a specific sector are well co-ordinated, and preferably, one and the<br />

same entity. This can prevent duplication, as well as helping to build up<br />

expertise in the evaluation <strong>of</strong> bids and awarding <strong>of</strong> funds;<br />

� Grant awards are <strong>of</strong>ten poorly monitored, and evaluations tend to be selfserving.<br />

Some experience in the UK suggests that different ‘delivery bodies’<br />

have sought to publicise claims <strong>of</strong> their efficacy which are not obviously<br />

substantiated by robust evidence, principally as a means to create the case for<br />

further funding support. Care needs to be taken to make evaluation processes<br />

clear and meaningful so that lessons can be learned to improve value for<br />

money in subsequent funding rounds;<br />

� Evaluation is crucial. This is public money, and as such, should be accounted<br />

for properly. The evaluation should take place against clear criteria. Cases <strong>of</strong><br />

quality, independent evaluations <strong>of</strong> schemes are relatively rare. There has, as<br />

far as we are aware, been no evaluation <strong>of</strong> the Environment Fund, though<br />

some schemes within it have reported on their activities. It goes without saying<br />

that fund evaluation should not be undertaken wholly by those whose<br />

schemes have been supported;<br />

� There may be a tendency for grant funds to ‘over-support’ projects, especially<br />

where a general pool <strong>of</strong> bids is rather poor, or where those making the award<br />

are insufficiently knowledgeable to judge the likely costs <strong>of</strong> projects (and what<br />

represents value for money). Where awards are being made, it is important to<br />

involve people who have an understanding <strong>of</strong> costs and value for money<br />

issues;<br />

� Those making grant awards frequently allow private sector partners to be less<br />

than open with their accounts, even though, in some cases, the principle <strong>of</strong><br />

the funding might be that the project would not have been viable without<br />

support. The cloak <strong>of</strong> ‘commercial confidentiality’ should not extend to the<br />

accounts <strong>of</strong> projects which rely on public support for their existence, at least<br />

where the awarding body is concerned. Grant awarding bodies need such<br />

information to improve their understanding <strong>of</strong> costs in the areas they seek to<br />

make awards;<br />

� Grant funding can be too ‘ad-hoc’. Some services, which might appear<br />

‘superfluous’, but which are actually essential and good value for money,<br />

29/09/09


929<br />

might be axed in times <strong>of</strong> funding cuts. Arguably, such services should not be<br />

‘grant funded’, but where they are, longer-term commitments should be made,<br />

alongside detailed delivery plans and reviews to ensure efficiency <strong>of</strong> delivery.<br />

This also highlights the role <strong>of</strong> evaluation in seeking to ensure that priorities<br />

are understood;<br />

� The flip side <strong>of</strong> this is that projects which are supported should, where it is<br />

reasonable to expect this, be capable <strong>of</strong> continuing beyond the grant funding<br />

period. This is especially important with support for fledgling waste projects.<br />

Projects need to be able to demonstrate that there is a realistic prospect for<br />

continuing beyond the period where grant money is spent;<br />

� As public funding the positive outcomes are very <strong>of</strong>ten described in case<br />

studies <strong>of</strong> each funded project and readily available on the funding body’s<br />

website. However, publication <strong>of</strong> raw data is lacking. Also, although it is<br />

considered very likely that funding bodies assess the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> their<br />

funding stream no evidence <strong>of</strong> this type <strong>of</strong> report being made publicly available<br />

has been found;<br />

The variety <strong>of</strong> schemes that are run, in terms <strong>of</strong> size <strong>of</strong> the fund available, the quality<br />

<strong>of</strong> applicants and the funding rate, makes evaluating grant funding in generic terms<br />

challenging. This would infer that looking at specific cases is a more effective<br />

evaluation method, and in theory this may be the case, but the lack <strong>of</strong> available data,<br />

due to funding body’s reluctance to release specific details, makes this impossible.<br />

With regards to the Environment Fund in Ireland feedback from the waste<br />

management industry suggests that there is a lack <strong>of</strong> support towards the private<br />

sector, despite there being no barriers in the legislation in funding private operators.<br />

Instead, the fund has developed into a source <strong>of</strong> money mainly for public sector<br />

projects or those <strong>of</strong> other bodies.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


TECHNICAL ANNEXES<br />

930<br />

29/09/09


61.0 Appraisal <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment<br />

Options<br />

Options appraisal can be achieved through using both quantitative and qualitative<br />

assessment approaches. The merits and drawbacks <strong>of</strong> different approaches are the<br />

subject <strong>of</strong> some considerable debate.<br />

There is a clear tendency in most areas <strong>of</strong> public policy to favour, increasingly,<br />

quantitative appraisal <strong>of</strong> options. Policies are increasingly subjected to Regulatory<br />

Impact Assessments (RIAs), or to Extended Impact Assessments (EIAs), and there is<br />

considerable emphasis placed upon quantitative evidence which can be used to<br />

support (or indeed, reject) the case for a particular policy proposal.<br />

61.1 Assessment Approaches<br />

In the field <strong>of</strong> waste management, two particular approaches to quantitative<br />

assessment are prominent. They are life-cycle assessment (LCA) and cost-benefit<br />

analysis (CBA). These two approaches have both merits and shortcomings, and these<br />

are discussed below.<br />

61.1.1 Life Cycle Assessment<br />

The approach <strong>of</strong> LCA is based upon quantification <strong>of</strong> the flows <strong>of</strong> pollutants as a<br />

means to understand their impact upon the environment. The aim is to estimate the<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> the options being considered (the scope <strong>of</strong> the study is usually defined, as<br />

are the system boundaries) upon the environment by aggregating the flows <strong>of</strong><br />

pollutants across the whole life-cycle. Once the pollutants have been aggregated,<br />

weightings are applied to them to estimate the relative contribution <strong>of</strong> the options to<br />

different impact categories (such as global warming, air acidification, aquatic toxicity,<br />

etc.). Some <strong>of</strong> LCA’s main flaws were laid out over a decade ago by Ayres, who argued<br />

that, ‘LCA has no (or even negative) utility if the underlying physical data are wrong<br />

with respect to critical pollutants.’ 1142 The obvious truth content <strong>of</strong> this statement<br />

must be set against the enormity <strong>of</strong> the challenge facing any LCA practitioner,<br />

especially one who is examining a municipal waste management system.<br />

Any municipal waste management system is potentially complex. The options<br />

available to a municipality include:<br />

931<br />

� Options in respect <strong>of</strong> collection systems:<br />

o Which materials to collect separately?<br />

o With how many passes?<br />

o With or without a requirement for subsequent mechanical separation?<br />

o In which vehicles?<br />

1142 R.U. Ayres (1995) Life cycle Analysis: A Critique. Resources, Conservation and Recycling 14, 199-<br />

223<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


932<br />

29/09/09<br />

o At what frequency?<br />

o In what type <strong>of</strong> container?<br />

o With what type <strong>of</strong> incentive?<br />

o On what rounds?<br />

� Properly understood, collection systems need to consider each <strong>of</strong> these<br />

separately, not as though they were discrete questions demanding separate<br />

answers;<br />

� Options in respect <strong>of</strong> transfer points for subsequent bulking / onward transfer<br />

/ treatment;<br />

o How many will there be?<br />

o Where should they be located?<br />

Once again, these questions are connected to other questions concerning the nature,<br />

scale and type <strong>of</strong> treatment option to be used (ideally, the materials being collected<br />

are either treated where they are ‘bulked up’, or they are bulked up in such a way as<br />

to optimise the onward transport for subsequent treatment);<br />

� Options in respect <strong>of</strong> the treatment <strong>of</strong> materials;<br />

o Will any materials be composted at home?<br />

o Which materials will be re-used, and if so, to what use will they be put?<br />

o What type <strong>of</strong> mechanical separation technique will be used for dry<br />

recyclables if any?<br />

o If biowastes are being collected separately, will the treatment be<br />

aerobic or anaerobic?<br />

� If aerobic:<br />

• Will it be enclosed, or open air?<br />

• If enclosed, what type <strong>of</strong> technology will be used?<br />

• How long will the material be treated for?<br />

• What type <strong>of</strong> abatement equipment <strong>of</strong> exhaust gases will<br />

be used?<br />

� If anaerobic:<br />

• What type <strong>of</strong> treatment will be used?<br />

• What type <strong>of</strong> abatement equipment will be used?<br />

• Will the residue be treated in an aerobic phase after<br />

being digested?<br />

• How will waste waters be dealt with?<br />

o How will residual waste be treated?<br />

� Sent untreated to landfill?<br />

� Sent<br />

� Options in respect <strong>of</strong> the products manufactured from materials collected for<br />

recycling / composting / digestion<br />

o Are recovered recyclables manufactured into the same products from<br />

which they were derived?<br />

o Where will this happen (how far will they travel?);<br />

o To what use will compost / digestate be put, and what does this imply<br />

for ‘avoided products’?<br />

� Options in respect <strong>of</strong> energy generation;<br />

o Will biogas from landfills / digesters be used as:


933<br />

� Biogas for vehicle fuels?<br />

� Electricity generation?<br />

� Heat generation?<br />

� Combined heat and power?<br />

� Use in hydrogen cells?<br />

o Will combustion / thermal treatment processes generate:<br />

� Electricity?<br />

� Heat?<br />

� Combined heat and power?<br />

� Syngas for chemical synthesis (thermal treatment)?<br />

� heat, syngas, etc.)<br />

o Where RDF is produced, will it be used for:<br />

� Combustion in a fluidized bed incinerator<br />

� Combustion in a cement kiln<br />

� Combustion in a power station<br />

� Options in respect <strong>of</strong> residues from thermal processes?<br />

The point being made is that there are an almost infinite number <strong>of</strong> possible<br />

arrangements (and the possibilities are increasing in number all the time). So Ayres’<br />

apparently obvious statement becomes all the more significant when the sheer<br />

complexity <strong>of</strong> the problem being addressed is understood.<br />

The weaknesses <strong>of</strong> LCA in the context <strong>of</strong> waste management options appraisal have<br />

been detailed elsewhere. 1143 Briefly, the key issues are:<br />

� The accuracy / validity <strong>of</strong> the weightings attributed to pollutants in impact<br />

assessment categories;<br />

� The tendency to seek datasets for the sake <strong>of</strong> completeness without<br />

necessarily assessing the quality <strong>of</strong> the data, its vintage, or its relevance;<br />

� Insensitivity to location <strong>of</strong> the emissions (and hence, the potential receptors);<br />

� Insensitivity to time (implying that effects related to concentration are not<br />

captured);<br />

� Inability to account for effects not related to the flow <strong>of</strong> pollutants (such as<br />

disamenity); and<br />

� Aggregation <strong>of</strong> impacts across impact assessment categories.<br />

Each <strong>of</strong> these issues raises problems for the practitioner. In addition, it is clear that<br />

some assumptions have a significant effect on results. Some <strong>of</strong> these are discussed<br />

below with regard to CBAs, which are similarly affected by the assumptions made.<br />

1143 D. Hogg (2004) Costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> Bioprocesses in <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, in P. Lens, B.<br />

Hamelers, H. Hoitink and W. Bidlingmaier (2004) Resource Recovery and Reuse in Organic Solid<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, London: IWA Publishing, pp.95-121.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


61.1.2 Cost benefit Analysis<br />

Cost benefit analysis takes a somewhat different approach. In cost benefit analysis,<br />

the underlying philosophy is to translate impacts into a common metric – that <strong>of</strong><br />

money. Economists are <strong>of</strong>ten keen to make the distinction between valuing<br />

somewhat controversial things – for example, life, or landscapes – and valuing<br />

preferences for (or against) them. At one level, therefore, the approach would appear<br />

to have something in its favour relative to LCA in that it enables various different<br />

types <strong>of</strong> impact across different media quite readily aggregated in a common,<br />

monetary, unit. Another positive feature <strong>of</strong> CBA is that it enables cost to be included<br />

in the analysis. LCAs clearly cannot do this without significant modification.<br />

Through the process <strong>of</strong> discounting, time is accounted for in CBA. This takes on<br />

particular significance when comparing different treatment options with significantly<br />

different pr<strong>of</strong>iles relating to emissions over time. This is a consideration that is not<br />

available to LCA practitioners, though many LCA practitioners appreciate the<br />

significance <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

CBAs also tend to be more concerned with impacts than are LCAs. As mentioned<br />

above, LCAs are insensitive to issues <strong>of</strong> pollutant concentration. In order to evaluate<br />

impacts, economists rely upon credible dose-response relationships. This also<br />

requires some understanding <strong>of</strong> how emissions from a given process can be<br />

translated into concentrations to which receptors are exposed. A major plus point,<br />

therefore – the attempt to estimate actual impacts – immediately becomes a<br />

weakness. There are relatively few pollutants for which quality dose-response<br />

relationships exist. For others, the way pollutants follow particular pathways is not<br />

especially well known so even the exposure term is unclear. For some pollutants,<br />

even where exposures are well known, the dose-response relationships are subject to<br />

uncertainty (sometimes radically so, as exemplified by differences in US and EU<br />

perspectives on the threshold at which dioxins present a hazard to human health).<br />

On top <strong>of</strong> all this, even for those pollutants whose fate is relatively well-known (so the<br />

exposure term is relatively well understood), and those for which the dose-response<br />

relationships are tolerably well understood, there remain issues associated with the<br />

valuation process itself. Many outside the economics discipline criticise the approach<br />

to ‘valuing nature / health’ as ethically indefensible, though economists respond that<br />

choices as to how to make best use <strong>of</strong> scarce resources must be made. However,<br />

within the discipline, debate continues on issues such as how to value mortality and<br />

morbidity, what discount rate to use, etc.<br />

61.2 External Costs <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment<br />

The analysis <strong>of</strong> costs and benefits associated with residual waste treatment options is<br />

a subject which has been discussed in a range <strong>of</strong> studies. Many <strong>of</strong> these look not just<br />

934<br />

29/09/09


at landfill and incineration, but at recycling too. However, very few have looked at<br />

other non-landfill treatments for residual waste. 1144<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the key assumptions which influence the outcomes <strong>of</strong> such appraisals are<br />

outlined and discussed below. This discussion will highlight important methodological<br />

issues, serving to contextualise the subsequent review <strong>of</strong> specific studies.<br />

61.2.1 Methodological Issues Common to External Cost Appraisal <strong>of</strong> all<br />

Options<br />

In what follows, issues relating to the calculation <strong>of</strong> external costs <strong>of</strong> different residual<br />

waste options are considered. Firstly, a number <strong>of</strong> general comments are presented<br />

on the methodology applied in studies assessing <strong>of</strong> external costs.<br />

1) Most studies seem to use an approach based upon the use <strong>of</strong> unit damage costs<br />

(UDCs) to assess the harm caused by specific pollutants. Relatively few make use<br />

<strong>of</strong> ‘bottom up’ approaches in which the impact <strong>of</strong> emissions are modelled through<br />

dose-response functions applied to the locality in which an activity takes place.<br />

2) If the study is ‘top down’, the choice <strong>of</strong> unit damage costs becomes critical.<br />

Similarly, if the study is ‘bottom up’, the choice <strong>of</strong> dose-response functions, the<br />

way the dispersion <strong>of</strong> pollutants is modelled, and the nature <strong>of</strong> the location<br />

assumed for any activity all become important. The scope <strong>of</strong> the analysis (the<br />

range <strong>of</strong> the pollutants modelled) is <strong>of</strong> obvious significance in both cases. There<br />

do appear to be some discernable trends in this regard:<br />

� The range <strong>of</strong> pollutants to which a damage cost is assigned appears to be<br />

expanding over time. Earlier studies tended to focus on emissions <strong>of</strong> GHGs,<br />

NOx, PM and SOx, whilst more recent studies have become more ambitious in<br />

their attempt to capture a range <strong>of</strong> externalities. A problem here is that neither<br />

the unit damage costs, nor the dose response functions which typically<br />

underpin studies from which UDCs are derived, are known with certainty.<br />

There remains considerable uncertainty concerning the effects <strong>of</strong> a range <strong>of</strong><br />

pollutants upon human health. It barely needs stating that the long-term<br />

consequences <strong>of</strong> some activities have barely been touched upon;<br />

� The significance <strong>of</strong> specific types <strong>of</strong> pollutant in the overall assessment <strong>of</strong><br />

damages appears to be changing. GHGs may be becoming more important,<br />

even as the damages associated with SOx, NOx, PM10, etc. are being<br />

downplayed. PM2.5 may become more important in analyses as awareness<br />

1144 J.C. Powell, David Pearce and Inger Brisson (1995) Valuation for Life cycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Options, CSERGE Working Paper WM 95-07; Coopers & Lybrand, CSERGE and EFTEC<br />

(1997) Cost-Benefit Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Different Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems: Objectives and<br />

Instruments for the Year 2000, Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Communities.); Broome, E., P. Vaze and D. Hogg (1999) Beyond the Bin: the Economics <strong>of</strong> Recycling,<br />

Final Report to <strong>Waste</strong> Watch.; COWI (2000) External Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfill and Incineration, Final Report to<br />

the European Commission; Nolan ITU (2004) TBL Assessment <strong>of</strong> Garden Organics <strong>Management</strong>, Final<br />

Report to the NSW Dept <strong>of</strong> Environment and Conservation, Sustainability Programs Division, May<br />

2004.<br />

935<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


increases <strong>of</strong> the significance <strong>of</strong> the distinction between sub 10 micron<br />

particles;<br />

� Some attention is being given to the potential health effects– though we are<br />

not aware <strong>of</strong> any study which has attempted to make an assessment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

associated external costs – <strong>of</strong> bioaerosols from biological treatment plants;<br />

� The focus <strong>of</strong> the majority <strong>of</strong> studies – or at least, <strong>of</strong> the valuation element - is<br />

on the emissions to the atmosphere associated with different processes. The<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> processes on, for example, water pollution are generally not<br />

explored. This is <strong>of</strong> interest since few studies apply any discount factor to the<br />

emissions to atmosphere from processes which generate emissions over<br />

extended periods <strong>of</strong> time (such as landfilling, composting, anaerobic digestion,<br />

mechanical biological treatment, etc.). If a zero discount rate is being<br />

(implicitly) applied, it would be consistent to consider the emissions from<br />

landfills (and landfilled residues from incineration plants) over the longer term.<br />

Recent life-cycle studies suggest that if such emissions were, indeed, taken<br />

into account, they might become decisive in any analysis <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

performance, especially if a zero discount rate is applied; 1145<br />

3) Following from the above few studies appear to have applied a non-zero discount<br />

rate to account for the fact that the emissions from some processes occur over an<br />

extended period <strong>of</strong> time. The use <strong>of</strong> a non-zero rate would tend to have the effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> reducing, in relative significance, the following externalities:<br />

� Atmospheric emissions from landfills, MBT facilities, compost facilities,<br />

anaerobic digestion facilities;<br />

� The benefits associated from the capture <strong>of</strong> methane from landfills for energy<br />

generation;<br />

� Emissions to water and land from the landfilling <strong>of</strong> residues, whether these be<br />

from incinerator bottom ash, incinerator air pollution control residues,<br />

untreated refuse, MBT-treated residues, etc. However, only a few studies<br />

appear to have attributed any environmental cost to these; 1146<br />

� Emissions to air, land and water from the application <strong>of</strong> the products <strong>of</strong><br />

biological treatment (i.e. composts or digestion residuals) to land, as well as<br />

those from any ‘displaced products’.<br />

4) The way in which the flux <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gases is handled in the non-zero discount<br />

rate case may be very important for the final analysis, but extremely difficult to<br />

1145 See S. Hellweg (2000) Time- and Site-Dependent Life-Cycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> Thermal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Treatment Processes, Dissertation submitted to the Swiss Federal Institute Of Technology. AWS, IFIP &<br />

GUA (2000): Bewertung abfallwirtschaftlicher Maßnahmen mit dem Ziel der nachsorgefreien Deponie<br />

– BEWEND. Unpublished case study Institute for Water Quality and <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> TU Vienna,<br />

Institute for Public Finance and Infrastructure <strong>Policy</strong> TU Vienna & Gesellschaft für umfassende<br />

Analysen GmbH, Vienna, Austria.<br />

1146 See Nolan ITU (2004) TBL Assessment <strong>of</strong> garden organics management, Final Report to the NSW<br />

Dept <strong>of</strong> Environment and Conservation, Sustainability Programs Division, May 2004; G. Döberl, R.<br />

Huber, P.H. Brunner, M. Eder, R. Pierrard, W. Schönbäck, W. Frühwirth and H. Hutterer (2002) Longterm<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> waste management options - a new, integrated and goal-oriented approach, <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> & Research, 20 (4), pp. 311-327; E. Dijkgraaf, and H. Vollebergh (2004) Burn or bury? A<br />

social cost comparison <strong>of</strong> final waste disposal methods, Ecological Economics, 50, pp.233-247.<br />

936<br />

29/09/09


handle. The choice <strong>of</strong> discount rate, as well as changing the sensitivity <strong>of</strong> the<br />

damages assessed to the time period over which those emissions occur, should<br />

also change the unit damage costs associated with the key climate change gases<br />

and their relative significance since these gases have an effect which occurs over<br />

an extended period, and their residence times in the atmosphere vary.<br />

5) In bottom up studies, the value placed upon the different end-points associated<br />

with the effects <strong>of</strong> different pollutants will affect the analysis. Different studies<br />

resort, for example, to the use <strong>of</strong> values based upon the value <strong>of</strong> a statistical life<br />

(VSL), whereas others use the value <strong>of</strong> life-years lost approach (VLYL). Similarly, in<br />

top-down studies, the unit damage costs are likely to be high or lower (other things<br />

being equal) depending upon whether the study from which the unit damage costs<br />

are taken made use <strong>of</strong> VSL or VLYL; 1147<br />

6) Where a study considers the implications <strong>of</strong> energy recovery, and makes an<br />

assumption that the energy generated ‘displaces’ another source <strong>of</strong> energy, the<br />

net effects <strong>of</strong> the energy generation depend critically upon which source <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

the study assumes to be displaced. The ‘dirtier’ the displaced source, the more<br />

advantageous (in the analysis) the generation <strong>of</strong> energy appears.<br />

These issues are some <strong>of</strong> the critical ones in existing studies on the external costs <strong>of</strong><br />

waste management. They explain much <strong>of</strong> the variation between studies.<br />

61.2.2 Landfill<br />

Where landfilling is concerned, the majority <strong>of</strong> studies concentrate on air emissions.<br />

Of these, methane has, unsurprising, received most attention. Relatively few studies<br />

have sought to look at an expanded range <strong>of</strong> emissions, or at emissions to other<br />

media. In the external costs literature, it is usually assumed that leachate is well<br />

managed so that there are no relevant problematic emissions to land and water. This<br />

is a contentious (though simplifying) assumption, and it is almost certainly incorrect in<br />

the longer-term. 1148<br />

As regards methane emissions, the quantity <strong>of</strong> methane released to the atmosphere<br />

depends upon:<br />

937<br />

� The quantity generated in the landfill;<br />

� The quantity collected by gas collection systems;<br />

� The quantity <strong>of</strong> the uncollected methane which is oxidised as it passes through<br />

the cap, or its leachate; and<br />

� The efficiency <strong>of</strong> combustion processes in converting methane to carbon<br />

dioxide and carbon monoxide<br />

Each <strong>of</strong> these variables (with the possible exception <strong>of</strong> the last) is contested not least<br />

because each <strong>of</strong> the parameters is likely to vary over time (and space).<br />

1147 Value <strong>of</strong> Statistical Life or Value <strong>of</strong> Life Years Lost.<br />

1148 S. Hellweg (2000) Time- and Site-Dependent Life-Cycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> Thermal <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment<br />

Processes, Dissertation submitted to the Swiss Federal Institute Of Technology.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Landfills also emit other gases. Those which are generated in the early stages after<br />

materials are deposited in the landfill are not so well characterised as those collected<br />

from the landfill gas collection systems. Yet it seems reasonable to assume that in<br />

the period during which degradation is aerobic, that emissions <strong>of</strong> various pollutants<br />

will be significant. Most notable here may be ammonia emissions, which tend to<br />

occur early in degradation processes, and which appear to be associated with<br />

considerable damages. It might be added that in the UK, studies have hinted at a link<br />

between landfills and the incidence <strong>of</strong> birth defects in their vicinity. However, the<br />

strength <strong>of</strong> this association is not considered by government to be sufficiently strong<br />

to support any causal link, though the evidence is at least suggestive. 1149<br />

Landfills also lead to disamenity associated with dust, noise, odour, litter, etc. There<br />

have been a number <strong>of</strong> studies addressing the issue and one which sought to<br />

establish a meta-analysis <strong>of</strong> existing studies. The transferability <strong>of</strong> these results is not<br />

clear.<br />

As discussed above, the issue <strong>of</strong> discounting should be important in the context <strong>of</strong><br />

emissions from landfills. However, this issue has not been given the attention it<br />

deserves from an economic perspective. Indeed, an Austrian study appears to have<br />

assumed a zero discount rate in the analysis even though different time horizons for<br />

the analysis were considered. 1150 Indeed, to our knowledge, all studies which have<br />

assessed the external costs <strong>of</strong> landfill have applied a zero discount rate. This is true<br />

<strong>of</strong> a recent UK study, even though the agreed approach <strong>of</strong> UK Government is to use a<br />

discount rate which declines, over time, from its early rate <strong>of</strong> 3.5% per annum (but<br />

not falling to zero). 1151 Where life-cycle studies are used to provide the emissions<br />

inventory, the use <strong>of</strong> a zero discount rate assumption requires a decision to be made<br />

about what the time horizon should be for time-dependent processes. In the absence<br />

<strong>of</strong> a discount rate, this decision becomes arbitrary, and it usually made on an<br />

arbitrary basis.<br />

As discussed previously, to the extent that landfills generate energy, the issue <strong>of</strong><br />

‘which source is being displaced’ assumes considerable relevance.<br />

61.2.3 Incineration<br />

As with other treatments, the focus <strong>of</strong> external costs <strong>of</strong> incineration has been on air<br />

emissions. Different studies seek to capture differing ranges <strong>of</strong> pollutants. Evidently,<br />

the coverage <strong>of</strong> pollutants will affect the analysis.<br />

1149 See Paul Elliott et al (2001) Risk <strong>of</strong> Adverse Birth Outcomes in Populations Living Near Landfill<br />

Sites, British Medical Journal, 2001, Vol 323, pp.363-68. P. Elliott, S Richardson, J J Abellan, A<br />

Thomson, C de Hoogh, L Jarup, and D J Briggs (2009) Geographic density <strong>of</strong> landfill sites and risk <strong>of</strong><br />

congenital anomalies in England, Occup. Environ. Med. 2009, Vol. 66, pp.81-89.<br />

1150 G. Döberl, R. Huber, P.H. Brunner, M. Eder, R. Pierrard, W. Schönbäck, W. Frühwirth and H.<br />

Hutterer (2002) Long-term assessment <strong>of</strong> waste management options - a new, integrated and goaloriented<br />

approach, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> & Research, 20 (4), pp. 311-327.<br />

1151 HM Customs & Excise (2004) Combining the Government’s two heath and environment studies to<br />

calculate estimates for the external costs <strong>of</strong> landfill and incineration, December 2004.<br />

938<br />

29/09/09


Other key variables <strong>of</strong> importance include the following:<br />

939<br />

� The emissions assumed to result from the incineration process itself –<br />

incinerators (as with most treatments) are not completely homogeneous. For<br />

example, with regard to NOx emissions (which are a source <strong>of</strong> secondary<br />

particulates), some countries routinely require use <strong>of</strong> selective catalytic<br />

reduction <strong>of</strong> NOx whereas many others do not (yet still may be able to meet<br />

Incineration Directive standards using non-catalytic methods and flue gas<br />

recirculation). Generally, incinerators’ performance needs to be understood in<br />

the context <strong>of</strong> knowledge <strong>of</strong> the flue gas cleaning system and <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

materials received at the plant;<br />

� the nature <strong>of</strong> the energy recovery process, and hence the degree to which<br />

<strong>of</strong>fsetting emissions can be attributed to the process. There appears to be a<br />

marked difference in the performance <strong>of</strong> some Scandinavian facilities, where<br />

the efficiency <strong>of</strong> heat recovery is very high, and those <strong>of</strong> the other EU Member<br />

States where energy is usually recovered as electricity, with relatively low<br />

efficiencies. At the same time, it is not entirely clear whether the higher energy<br />

efficiencies possible where heat recovery is the objective should be deemed<br />

more superior from an environmental standpoint since generally, more fuel is<br />

required to generate a kilowatt hour <strong>of</strong> electricity than is required to generate<br />

a kilowatt hour <strong>of</strong> heat. Much depends upon the avoided sources <strong>of</strong> each;<br />

� the degree to which it is assumed that materials are recycled at the facility (for<br />

example, steel and aluminium extracted from bottom ash, or bottom ash<br />

recycled for use as construction material);<br />

� the way in which landfilled residues are treated, particularly the air pollution<br />

control residues which contain hazardous components, and possibly the<br />

bottom ash also if this is also <strong>of</strong> a hazardous nature.<br />

Another issue which may be important for the analysis – especially if impacts are<br />

being discounted (as they should be) is whether the materials used in the<br />

construction <strong>of</strong> the plant are included in the analysis. Incinerators are complex pieces<br />

<strong>of</strong> engineering and they operate for around two decades. Whilst life-cycle studies<br />

suggest a small proportion <strong>of</strong> overall burdens are associated with materials used in<br />

construction, the application <strong>of</strong> a non-zero discount rate in a CBA might change this<br />

considerably. Probably <strong>of</strong> lesser importance are the inputs to the process, including<br />

gas cleaning chemicals.<br />

Of relevance to this discussion is the fact that several countries have instated landfill<br />

taxes in order to try to increase the costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling so as to drive materials away<br />

from disposal. In theory, this ought to be based upon a view that disposal is ‘worse<br />

than’ recycling. The majority <strong>of</strong> cost-benefit studies tend to support this perspective<br />

for most dry recyclables. 1152 Interestingly, however, fewer countries have applied<br />

1152 Inger Brisson and Jane Powell (1995) Dump or burn? – the assessment <strong>of</strong> social costs and<br />

benefits <strong>of</strong> waste disposal, CSERGE, University College <strong>of</strong> London and University <strong>of</strong> East Anglia; J.C.<br />

Powell, David Pearce and Inger Brisson (1995) Valuation for life cycle assessment <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management options, CSERGE Working Paper WM 95-07; J.C. Powell, A.L. Craighill, J.P. Parfitt and R.K.<br />

Turner (1996) A lifecycle assessment and economic valuation <strong>of</strong> recycling, Journal <strong>of</strong> Environmental<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


taxes on incineration despite the fact that much <strong>of</strong> the literature suggests that unless<br />

heat is recovered with a high level <strong>of</strong> efficiency, the external costs <strong>of</strong> incineration are<br />

not so different from those <strong>of</strong> landfills. 1153 Other studies are more positive regarding<br />

incineration, though neither <strong>of</strong> the two referenced below applies a positive discount<br />

rate in the analysis). 1154<br />

61.2.4 Other Residual Treatments<br />

There are not many studies appraising the options in respect <strong>of</strong> other residual<br />

treatments. A summary <strong>of</strong> the issues relating to appraisal <strong>of</strong> these treatments is given<br />

below.<br />

61.2.4.1 Advanced Thermal Treatment<br />

ATT systems are likely to be affected by similar considerations as incinerators. Key<br />

differences may be as follows (and these differences are likely to be specific to<br />

specific configurations);<br />

1. Some systems may be configured so as to produce syngas from waste materials<br />

rather than to combust the gas and generate energy. This means that the effect is<br />

not to displace energy per se, but other feedstocks in chemical synthesis. To the<br />

extent that these feedstocks are produced using processes which are<br />

environmentally harmful, such substitution will be beneficial;<br />

2. Although some incinerators make use <strong>of</strong> post-treatment processes to minimize<br />

the impacts <strong>of</strong> landfilling air pollution control residues, in some high temperature<br />

processes, the vitrification <strong>of</strong> such residues is integrated into the process. This<br />

would imply that to the extent that landfilling <strong>of</strong> such residues without such<br />

Planning and <strong>Management</strong>, Vol 39 (1), pp.97-112; I.E. Brisson (1997) Assessing the <strong>Waste</strong> Hierarchy<br />

– a Social Cost-Benefit Analysis <strong>of</strong> Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in the European Union,<br />

http:/www.akf/eng/waste1.htm; Coopers & Lybrand, CSERGE and EFTEC (1997) Cost-Benefit Analysis<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Different Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Systems: Objectives and Instruments for the Year 2000,<br />

Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications <strong>of</strong> the European Communities.); E. Broome, P. Vaze and D.<br />

Hogg (1999) Beyond the bin: the economics <strong>of</strong> recycling, Final Report to <strong>Waste</strong> Watch.; Nolan ITU<br />

(2004) TBL Assessment <strong>of</strong> garden organics management, Final Report to the NSW Dept <strong>of</strong><br />

Environment and Conservation, Sustainability Programs Division, May 2004.<br />

1153 COWI (2000) External Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfill and Incineration, Final Report to the European Commission;<br />

HM Customs & Excise (2004) Combining the Government’s two heath and environment studies to<br />

calculate estimates for the external costs <strong>of</strong> landfill and incineration, December 2004; E. Dijkgraaf,<br />

and H. Vollebergh (2004) Burn or bury? A social cost comparison <strong>of</strong> final waste disposal methods,<br />

Ecological Economics, 50, pp.233-247; E. Dijkgraaf and H. Volleberegh (2005) Literature review <strong>of</strong><br />

social costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> waste disposal and recycling, in (2005) Rethinking the <strong>Waste</strong> Hierachy,<br />

EAI: Copenhagen, pp. 80-98.<br />

1154 J-O, Sundqvist et al (2002) Hur skall hushallsavfallet tas omhand – utvardering av olika<br />

behandlingsmetoder (How shall municipal solid waste be disposed – assessment <strong>of</strong> different<br />

treatment methods) Stockholm February 2002. IVL report B 1462; G. Döberl, R. Huber, P.H. Brunner,<br />

M. Eder, R. Pierrard, W. Schönbäck, W. Frühwirth and H. Hutterer (2002) Long-term assessment <strong>of</strong><br />

waste management options - a new, integrated and goal-oriented approach, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> &<br />

Research, 20 (4), pp. 311-327.<br />

940<br />

29/09/09


treatment may give rise to damages, some reduction in the external costs <strong>of</strong><br />

landfilling such residues could be achieved;<br />

3. As regards the energy efficiency <strong>of</strong> such processes, some have taken the view that<br />

unless gas engines are used to generate energy from the energy carrying gases<br />

derived from pyrolysis / gasification, the net conversion <strong>of</strong> energy may be less<br />

than is the case with conventional mass burn incineration. Energy efficiencies are<br />

significant in the analysis, the more so if it is assumed that the source <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

which might be displaced is ‘less clean’. If gases are used in co-firing <strong>of</strong> power<br />

stations, higher efficiencies may be achieved;<br />

4. The design <strong>of</strong> the process itself may lead to lower emissions into raw flue gas with<br />

the result being that either emissions <strong>of</strong> cleaned flue gas are, other things being<br />

equal, improved relative to incineration, or that the expenditure on flue gas<br />

cleaning to achieve a given standard may be lower with ATT than with<br />

conventional incinerators.<br />

It should be made clear that because the processes being considered tend to be<br />

proprietary ones, the above comments are intended to apply to ‘possible<br />

configurations’, and they do not necessarily apply equally to all ATT processes.<br />

Furthermore, as stated earlier, the track record <strong>of</strong> ATT facilities for treating raw<br />

residual waste is not well established in Europe.<br />

61.2.4.2 MBT (basic stabilisation)<br />

Basic stabilization systems rely, in the main, on reducing the biodegradability <strong>of</strong><br />

material prior to landfilling. In this system, it is assumed that following mechanical<br />

treatment, the waste materials are subjected to an aerobic stabilization process with<br />

the aim being to reduce the potential for gas generation when the material is<br />

deposited in, or possibly on, a landfill. Some ferrous metals and perhaps some nonferrous<br />

metals may be extracted during the process, but the mass <strong>of</strong> material<br />

landfilled is essentially equal to the mass <strong>of</strong> material received minus the loss <strong>of</strong><br />

moisture and the mass loss due to the degradation <strong>of</strong>, principally, more rapidly<br />

degraded carbon fractions.<br />

The degree to which this represents an improvement on sending materials to landfill<br />

in an untreated form depends upon:<br />

1. The extent to which one believes that landfills fail to operate in a well-behaved<br />

manner, in particular, whether one believes that they:<br />

a. Do generate problematic emissions before gas capture systems are<br />

effectively operational;<br />

b. Fail to capture the majority <strong>of</strong> methane emitted over the time during<br />

which emissions from the waste occur;<br />

c. Generate relatively little energy from waste as a result;<br />

d. Generate problematic leachate;<br />

2. Whether the level <strong>of</strong> stabilization attained through the process is sufficient to<br />

ensure that residual methane emissions from landfilled waste are effectively<br />

reduced to close to zero (and this may imply active management);<br />

3. The level <strong>of</strong> abatement <strong>of</strong>, in particular, ammonia and more harmful VOCs (as<br />

opposed to less harmful ones emitted by bi<strong>of</strong>ilters) during the stabilization<br />

process; and<br />

941<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


4. The degree to which materials (especially metals) are recovered, and recovered in<br />

a useful form for recycling; and<br />

5. The degree to which other potential hazards associated with landfills are likely to<br />

be problematic in future, and he degree to which stabilization might minimize<br />

these.<br />

Each <strong>of</strong> these issues influences the degree to which stabilization contributes<br />

positively to the outcomes.<br />

Examining one <strong>of</strong> these more closely, it is clear that as regards greenhouse gas<br />

emissions (GHGs), when compared to landfilling <strong>of</strong> untreated waste, basic<br />

stabilization processes, with residues being landfilled, exhibit the following<br />

performance characteristics:<br />

� Less <strong>of</strong> the carbon is transformed into methane, and the majority is transformed<br />

into carbon dioxide, a far less potent greenhouse gas. Other things being equal,<br />

this means that the greenhouse gas emissions from the process (including the<br />

landfilling <strong>of</strong> the residues) will not be so harmful;<br />

� The absence <strong>of</strong> methane generation for subsequent capture for energy recovery<br />

implies no displacement <strong>of</strong> fossil carbon by the stabilization process by means <strong>of</strong><br />

energy generation. Other things being equal, this means that the greenhouse gas<br />

emissions from the process (including the landfilling <strong>of</strong> the residues) will be more<br />

damaging than for untreated landfilling;<br />

� On the other hand, stabilization processes would, typically, recover some<br />

materials such as steel even in their most basic configuration. This would imply<br />

recovery <strong>of</strong> energy embodied in materials, improving the greenhouse gas balance<br />

<strong>of</strong> the stabilization process;<br />

� Finally, the degradation <strong>of</strong> carbon is likely to occur more quickly under the more<br />

controlled conditions in a stabilization process. Hence, the time pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong><br />

emissions is such that proportionately more <strong>of</strong> the emissions occur earlier in time.<br />

The effect <strong>of</strong> discounting will tend to make the impact <strong>of</strong> these earlier emissions<br />

more important. Consequently, this would tend to increase the impact <strong>of</strong> the<br />

stabilization process relative to landfill <strong>of</strong> untreated waste where GHGs are<br />

concerned.<br />

It can be seen that a fairly complex range <strong>of</strong> issues affects performance in this one<br />

area. What is clear, however, is that in the overall system – stabilization plus<br />

landfilling – the majority <strong>of</strong> GHG emissions is shifted into the stabilization process.<br />

The emissions in the landfilling phase are likely to be less significant, and are likely to<br />

occur further into the future (because the remaining carbon is, by definition, <strong>of</strong> a<br />

more slowly degrading nature). Consequently, it seems reasonable to argue that<br />

landfilling stabilized waste is less harmful than landfilling treated waste.<br />

61.2.4.3 MBT (dry stabilisation, RDF to cement kiln)<br />

In this configuration, it is assumed that input materials are first treated mechanically<br />

(to render the material easier to treat aerobically) and then subjected to a process<br />

where the material is dried using both the heat from aerobic degradation processes,<br />

and the air from the aeration <strong>of</strong> the total mass <strong>of</strong> material.<br />

The performance <strong>of</strong> dry stabilisation processes are likely to be improved, in relative<br />

terms, if:<br />

942<br />

29/09/09


1. As described above (for basic stabilisation), the landfilling <strong>of</strong> untreated wastes<br />

performs relatively poorly;<br />

2. Again as described above, the abatement <strong>of</strong> ammonia and VOCs is efficient;<br />

3. Because the energy recovery process gives rise to ash and air pollution control<br />

residues in the form <strong>of</strong> clinker, the performance relative to incineration is<br />

improved where it is believed that landfilling <strong>of</strong> air pollution control residues from<br />

incinerators gives rise to environmental damage;<br />

4. Where the process <strong>of</strong> energy recovery through RDF utilisation clearly displaces<br />

less clean energy sources, this may improve relative performance. This issue is<br />

not straightforward as many cement kilns are beginning to utilise a range <strong>of</strong><br />

wastes (so the time may come where one waste simply replaces another, at the<br />

margin);<br />

5. Where the cement kiln itself is equipped with quality flue gas abatement. This may<br />

be <strong>of</strong> concern regarding more volatile heavy metals such as mercury, though<br />

equally, the significance <strong>of</strong> this must be contextualised by the mercury content <strong>of</strong><br />

incoming wastes;<br />

6. Some materials (e.g. ferrous metals, non-ferrous metals) are recovered with the<br />

ability to substitute for primary materials whose production incurs environmental<br />

damages;<br />

7. Any landfilled residues are biologically stable.<br />

These issues are among the key variables likely to affect the environmental<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> a treatment / disposal method based around dry stabilisation.<br />

Evidently, the nature <strong>of</strong> input wastes is also important in determining the nature <strong>of</strong>,<br />

for example, the RDF fraction which may be derived, and hence, the potential for, for<br />

example, energy recovery through combustion <strong>of</strong> the RDF.<br />

61.2.4.4 MBT (separation <strong>of</strong> some dry recyclables, AD <strong>of</strong> biowaste, and possibly<br />

RDF to third party)<br />

Several facilities are now in operation where the biological treatment aspect <strong>of</strong> the<br />

MBT process involves anaerobic digestion (AD). Facilities utilising dry and wet AD<br />

processes now exist. Evidently, in such processes, there may be advantages in<br />

ensuring that the costs <strong>of</strong> the AD equipment itself are reduced through the separation<br />

<strong>of</strong> a fraction consisting primarily <strong>of</strong> organic wastes suitable for digestion. This may<br />

occur through, for example, using screen undersieves for the digester since, for<br />

example, the food waste fraction <strong>of</strong> waste tends to be concentrated in small particle<br />

size fractions.<br />

As mechanical separation processes improve, it is becoming possible to consider<br />

facilities where residual waste is treated:<br />

1. Mechanically to separate out:<br />

a. fractions for recycling. Fractions may include metals, glass, other inert<br />

materials, and some plastics;<br />

b. fractions for subsequent biological treatment;<br />

c. fractions for subsequent use as an RDF;<br />

2. Biologically (anaerobic), with a small size fraction being digested to produce<br />

biogas;<br />

3. Thermally, with an RDF fraction derived for subsequent use either in dedicated<br />

waste facilities, or existing industrial facilities;<br />

943<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


4. Biologically (aerobic), with residues being stabilised prior to landfilling /<br />

landscaping (where <strong>of</strong> requisite quality).<br />

Various different configurations are possible.<br />

The relative performance <strong>of</strong> such facilities is likely to be quite good irrespective <strong>of</strong> the<br />

assumptions made. The combination <strong>of</strong> materials recovery, energy recovery and<br />

stabilisation <strong>of</strong> biodegradable fractions is likely to give favourable outcomes as long<br />

as the abatement <strong>of</strong> relevant pollutants is efficient and as long as the materials<br />

recovered are <strong>of</strong> sufficient quality to be put to use in ways which displace materials <strong>of</strong><br />

a similar quality to those being recovered.<br />

The key issues for such facilities are likely to be their costs, and these will be<br />

determined to a considerable degree by various policy-related instruments in future.<br />

The fact that such processes are relatively new (albeit that digestion <strong>of</strong> mixed waste<br />

has taken place for decades) is likely to mean that policies are not yet well-adapted to<br />

accommodate them. Indeed, since they rely on various ‘outlets’ for their outputs,<br />

there are risks associated with these technologies in the current policy environment.<br />

It should also be said that such processes are still considered quite novel, and have<br />

not been without their technical problems (so there is a technology risk to be<br />

considered as well).<br />

61.3 Relevant Studies<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> studies have looked at the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> waste treatments, but<br />

few have looked at residual waste treatments other than landfill and incineration.<br />

Accordingly, the majority <strong>of</strong> the studies presented here focus on landfill and<br />

incineration. However, as shown in the list below, two reports assessing the costs and<br />

benefits <strong>of</strong> MBT in Ireland are also reviewed.<br />

Two <strong>of</strong> the major studies concerning the external costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

management, focusing on disposal systems, were funded by the UK Government. The<br />

studies are:<br />

944<br />

� The work underpinning the setting <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Tax, which majored on the<br />

externalities associated with landfills and incinerators (the CSERGE et al<br />

study); 1155 and<br />

� More recently, the body <strong>of</strong> work leading to the derivation <strong>of</strong> figures by HM<br />

Customs & Excise concerning the externalities <strong>of</strong> landfills and incinerators. 1156<br />

1155 CSERGE, Warren Spring Laboratory and EFTEL (1993) Externalities from Landfill and Incineration,<br />

London: HMSO.<br />

1156 This body <strong>of</strong> work includes work on emissions and health effects by Enviros (Enviros, University <strong>of</strong><br />

Birmingham, RPA Ltd., Open University and Maggie Thurgood (2004) <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environmental and<br />

Health Effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> and Similar <strong>Waste</strong>s, Final Report to<br />

Defra, March 2004), work on the external costs <strong>of</strong> waste management by Enviros and EFTEC (Enviros<br />

and EFTEC (2004) Valuation Of The External Costs And Benefits To Health And Environment Of <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> Options Final Report for Defra, December 2004) and a piece which brought together the<br />

data concerning emissions from the first study and data concerning the unit damage costs for the<br />

29/09/09


In addition to these UK focused studies, work undertaken elsewhere in Europe <strong>of</strong><br />

particular relevance includes:<br />

945<br />

� A literature review <strong>of</strong> social costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> waste disposal and recycling<br />

(the Dijkgraaf & Vollebergh study), which challenges the assumption that the<br />

waste hierarchy is always correct; 1157<br />

� A study for the European Commission on the economic valuation <strong>of</strong><br />

environmental externalities from landfill disposal and incineration <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

(the COWI study); 1158<br />

The final reports reviewed relate to the impacts arising from the use <strong>of</strong> landfill,<br />

incineration and MBT for residual waste.<br />

� The first <strong>of</strong> these is a 2007 report for Greenstar on waste policy, planning and<br />

regulation in Ireland by Eunomia and Tobin. 1159<br />

� The second report, from 2008, by the same authors, for the same client,<br />

focuses on the potential role <strong>of</strong> MBT in meeting Ireland’s waste targets. 1160<br />

A forthcoming Regulatory Impact Analysis has been developed for both a levy on<br />

plastic bags, and a levy on certain waste facilities. The study also considers the<br />

external costs <strong>of</strong> the waste treatment options under consideration. However, the<br />

studies mentioned in the work are all covered in this review (as well as some others).<br />

61.3.1 CSERGE et al (1993)<br />

This work was used in the run-up to the introduction <strong>of</strong> the Landfill Tax and was<br />

influential in the decisions made concerning the level at which the tax should be<br />

set. 1161 The aim was to understand the externalities associated with landfill and<br />

incineration.<br />

Although the study undertook a review <strong>of</strong> work carried out elsewhere in assessing<br />

disamenity associated with landfills, these were omitted in the quantification <strong>of</strong> the<br />

external costs. The study noted these could be ‘significant’ and therefore their<br />

omission would affect the results. Brisson and Pearce later suggested that employing<br />

benefits transfer techniques from US studies would make a figure <strong>of</strong> £160 (about<br />

processes from the second study (see HM Customs & Excise (2004) Combining the Government’s Two<br />

Heath and Environment Studies to Calculate Estimates for the External Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfill and<br />

Incineration, December 2004).<br />

1157 E. Dijkgraaf and H. Vollebergh (2005) Literature review <strong>of</strong> social costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

disposal and recycling, in EAI (2005) Rethinking the <strong>Waste</strong> Hierachy, EAI: Copenhagen, pp. 80-98.<br />

1158 COWI (2000) External Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfill and Incineration, Final Report to the European Commission.<br />

1159 Eunomia and Tobin (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Planning and Regulation in Ireland, Final Report for<br />

Greenstar, Dublin, Ireland.<br />

1160 Eunomia and Tobin (2008) Meeting ireland’s <strong>Waste</strong> Targets: The role <strong>of</strong> MBT, Final Report for<br />

Greenstar, Dublin, Ireland.<br />

1161 For a more detailed review <strong>of</strong> this study, see E. Broome, P. Vaze and D. Hogg (2000) Beyond the<br />

Bin: The Economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, Final Report to <strong>Waste</strong> Watch.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


£173 in 1999 terms) per household per annum not unreasonable for houses within a<br />

4 mile radius <strong>of</strong> a landfill (which they also suggest is more or less equivalent to 3%<br />

depreciation on house values). 11621163<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> the study are shown in Table 61-1. Note that the study sought to<br />

measure the external costs associated with ‘typical tonnes’ <strong>of</strong> waste being landfilled<br />

or incinerated in different types <strong>of</strong> plant, and then averaged externalities across types<br />

<strong>of</strong> plant to arrive at a UK figure. It is clear from these results that the relative rates <strong>of</strong><br />

energy generation from the two types <strong>of</strong> facility are crucial determinants <strong>of</strong> their<br />

external costs as reported here. This is due to the significance <strong>of</strong> the pollution<br />

displacement assumed to occur as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the energy generation.<br />

The study assumed recovery <strong>of</strong> 664 kWh/tonne MSW for incineration and 79<br />

kWh/tonne MSW for landfills with energy recovery. Interestingly, the more recent<br />

study suggested figures <strong>of</strong> 581kWh and 203kWh respectively. 1164 If these figures had<br />

been used in the 1993 study, then examination <strong>of</strong> the ‘pollution displacement’ figures<br />

in Table 61-1 suggests that as a result <strong>of</strong> increased ‘pollution displacement’, landfills<br />

with energy recovery would have shown no negative externalities, and incinerators<br />

would have been attributed a reduced positive externality. Both results would have<br />

moved closer to zero.<br />

The external costs covered were:<br />

• for landfill, emissions <strong>of</strong> CO2 and CH4, casualties as well as CO2, NOx and<br />

particulate matter (PM) from transport <strong>of</strong> waste to the landfill, and reductions in<br />

CO2, NOx, SO2, PM and CH4 from displaced energy sources. A limited attempt was<br />

made to estimate leachate externalities whilst acknowledging the limitations <strong>of</strong><br />

the exercise; and<br />

• for incineration, emissions <strong>of</strong> CO2, NOx, SO2, PM, casualties as well as CO2, NOx<br />

and TSP from transport to the incinerator, and reductions in CO2, NOx, SO2, PM<br />

and CH4 from displaced energy sources.<br />

The ‘omission’ <strong>of</strong> other air pollutants might be important in such a study. The report<br />

noted that ‘This component <strong>of</strong> economic damage is therefore left unvalued in the<br />

current exercise, with the balance <strong>of</strong> probability being that such a value would be<br />

close to zero or zero’. The statement was based upon the views <strong>of</strong> the 1993 RCEP<br />

report on incinerators that comply with HMIP standards. There is a respectable body<br />

<strong>of</strong> science which casts doubt upon this perspective.<br />

1162 The lack <strong>of</strong> consideration <strong>of</strong> disamenity is more comprehensible when one sets the study in its<br />

policy context. In informing the level <strong>of</strong> a landfill tax being levied on waste, the fixed rather than<br />

variable nature <strong>of</strong> the disamenity externality could be used to justify not including the disamenity<br />

externality.<br />

1163 Inger Brisson and David Pearce (1995) Benefits Transfer for Disamenity from <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal,<br />

CSERGE Working Paper WM 95-06.<br />

1164 HM Customs & Excise (2004) Combining the Government’s Two Heath and Environment Studies<br />

to Calculate Estimates for the External Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfill and Incineration, December 2004.<br />

946<br />

29/09/09


Table 61-1: Externality Values for Landfill and Incineration (£/tonne waste other than disamenity)<br />

Global pollution<br />

947<br />

CO2<br />

CH4<br />

Air pollution<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

L1 a L2 b L3 c L4 d I1 e I2 f<br />

-0.32<br />

(-0.08 - -0.87)<br />

-2.36<br />

(-0.86 - -5.40)<br />

-0.46<br />

(-0.12 - -1.27)<br />

-1.36<br />

(-0.45 - -3.32)<br />

-0.32<br />

(-0.08 - -0.87)<br />

-2.36<br />

(-0.86 - -5.40)<br />

-0.46<br />

(-0.12 - -1.27)<br />

-1.36<br />

(-0.45 - -3.32)<br />

Conventional g n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.<br />

Conventional h n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.<br />

-2.55<br />

(-0.69 - -6.70)<br />

-2.55<br />

(-0.69 - -6.70)<br />

n.a. n.a.<br />

-1.62<br />

(-1.16 - -2.07)<br />

-2.01<br />

(-1.47 - -2.55)<br />

-1.51<br />

(-1.03 - -2.02)<br />

-1.14<br />

(-0.80 - -1.49)<br />

Toxics n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Not est. Not est.<br />

Transport impacts<br />

Pollution g<br />

Pollution h<br />

Accidents<br />

Leachate<br />

Pollution displacement g<br />

-0.09<br />

(-0.05 - -0.16)<br />

-0.10<br />

(-0.06 - -0.17)<br />

-0.23<br />

(-0.13 - -0.33)<br />

-0.45<br />

(0 - -0.9)<br />

0<br />

-0.09<br />

(-0.05 - -0.16)<br />

-0.10<br />

(-0.06 - -0.17)<br />

-0.23<br />

(-0.13 - -0.33)<br />

0<br />

+0.81<br />

(0.45 – 1.54)<br />

-0.38<br />

(-0.10 - -1.06)<br />

-0.46<br />

(-0.14 - -1.19)<br />

-0.55<br />

(-0.31 - -0.79)<br />

-0.45<br />

(0 - -0.9)<br />

0<br />

-0.38<br />

(-0.10 - -1.06)<br />

-0.46<br />

(-0.14 - -1.19)<br />

-0.55<br />

(-0.31 - -0.79)<br />

+0.81<br />

(0.45 – 1.54)<br />

-0.23<br />

(-0.11 - -0.52)<br />

-0.26<br />

(-0.12 - -0.57)<br />

-0.20<br />

(-0.11 - -0.29)<br />

-0.45<br />

(-0.11 - -0.93)<br />

-0.42<br />

(-0.15 - -1.03)<br />

-0.33<br />

(-0.18 - -0.48)<br />

0 n.a. n.a.<br />

+6.87<br />

(4.30 –<br />

+6.87<br />

(4.30 – 11.93)


Pollution displacement h 0<br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

Total g Range<br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

Total h Range<br />

Notes:<br />

948<br />

29/09/09<br />

L1 a L2 b L3 c L4 d I1 e I2 f<br />

+1.12<br />

(0.69 – 1.92)<br />

0<br />

+1.12<br />

(0.69 – 1.92)<br />

11.93)<br />

+9.40<br />

(6.49 –<br />

14.81)<br />

+9.40<br />

(6.49 – 14.81)<br />

Range -1.12 1.12 1.12 - -7.66 7.66 -4.63 4.63 - +0.80 +0.80 -1.35 1.35 1.35 - -9.02 9.02 -6.00 6.00 - +0.57 -5.28 5.28 - +9.86 -5.88 5.88 - +9.78<br />

Mean Mean j -3.4 3.4 3.45 3.4<br />

-1.33 1.33 1.33 -4.06 4.06 -1.94 1.94 +2.26 +2.26 +2.26 +2.01 +2.01<br />

+2.01<br />

Range -1.13 1.13 - -7.66 7.66 -4.91 4.91 - +1.17 -1.58 1.58 1.58 - -9.15 9.15 -5.89 5.89 - +0.91 -3.61 3.61 - +12.41 -4.27 4.27 - +12.32<br />

ME MEAN ME MEAN<br />

AN J -3.45 3.45 -1.03 1.03 1.03 -4.14 4.14 -1.72 1.72 +4.38 +4.38 +4.09<br />

+4.09<br />

a L1 is an existing urban landfill without energy recovery;<br />

b L2 is a new urban landfill with energy recovery;<br />

c L3 is an existing rural landfill without energy recovery;<br />

d L4 is a new rural landfill with energy recovery;<br />

e I1 is a new urban incinerator with energy recovery;<br />

f I2 is a new regional incinerator with energy recovery;<br />

g Conventional air pollution damage including UK based damage only;<br />

h Conventional air pollution damage including UK based as well as that in the rest <strong>of</strong> the ECE region;<br />

j Mean values do not necessarily reflect midpoint <strong>of</strong> ranges due to use <strong>of</strong> specific statistical techniques.<br />

Source: CSERGE, Warren Spring Laboratory and EFTEL (1993) Externalities from Landfill and Incineration, London: HMSO.


Transport externalities were incorporated into the assessment <strong>of</strong> externalities<br />

(through use <strong>of</strong> typical distances). It is somewhat debatable whether consideration <strong>of</strong><br />

externalities related to waste management facilities should consider transport<br />

externalities as part <strong>of</strong> the ‘process related’ externality (implying that, in some way, a<br />

particular facility always has associated with it a more or less well understood<br />

transport externality). To the extent that transport externalities can be altered through<br />

changed transportation modes as well as distances, such an analysis appears to<br />

obscure the possibilities for improvement, or indeed, for their being addressed by<br />

transport policies. Indeed, a number <strong>of</strong> instruments, notably, in the UK, the fuel duty<br />

escalator, have been introduced since the CSERGE work was undertaken. These<br />

effectively internalise transport related externalities to some extent. Consequently,<br />

their inclusion in ‘process-specific’ estimates <strong>of</strong> externalities is somewhat<br />

problematic. Several authors have opined that the UK fuel duty escalator internalises<br />

either completely, or to a significant degree, the external costs. This is an issue which<br />

we return to later. It is worth pointing out that since 1993, emissions <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

key pollutants on a per tonne per kilometre basis, notably NOx, have diminished<br />

significantly.<br />

The study made no attempt to consider the fact that emissions from landfill occur<br />

over an extended period <strong>of</strong> time. Methane is not emitted from landfills<br />

instantaneously, whereas the greenhouse gases from incinerators are. It would seem<br />

to be appropriate to apply a discount factor (or at least, to justify not applying one)<br />

where landfills are concerned. If it is deemed to be important to consider a non-zero<br />

discount rate, then making a simple distinction between biogenic and non-biogenic<br />

carbon, and assuming carbon dioxide from non-biogenic carbon is unimportant,<br />

cannot be justified. This is because the emissions <strong>of</strong> biogenic carbon dioxide occur at<br />

different rates from landfills and incinerators (and waste management facilities more<br />

generally). 1165<br />

61.3.2 HM Customs & Excise<br />

Just as the CSERGE et al study was used to inform the discussions concerning a<br />

landfill tax, so the work which culminated in the paper by HM Customs & Excise was<br />

important in informing the debate concerning an incineration tax. 1166 The final output<br />

– the HM Customs & Excise Report – is interesting for a number <strong>of</strong> reasons. These<br />

are discussed below.<br />

1165 D. Hogg et al (2002) Economic Assessment <strong>of</strong> Options for Dealing with Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong>,<br />

Report to DG Environment, European Commission, by Eunomia, Scuola Agraria del Parco di Monza,<br />

HDRA Consultants, ZREU and LDK.<br />

1166 Enviros, University <strong>of</strong> Birmingham, RPA Ltd., Open University and Maggie Thurgood (2004) <strong>Review</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> Environmental and Health Effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> and Similar<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>s, Final Report to Defra, March 2004); Enviros and EFTEC (2004) Valuation Of The External<br />

Costs And Benefits To Health And Environment Of <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options Final Report for Defra,<br />

December 2004.<br />

949<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


61.3.2.1 Restricted Range <strong>of</strong> Pollutants Attributed Values<br />

First, like the CSERGE et al study in 1993, the valuation <strong>of</strong> externalities was confined<br />

to a relatively narrow range <strong>of</strong> pollutants. The focus was on PM, SOx, NOx and VOCs,<br />

as well as CO2 and CH4. Given that the study identified estimates from the literature<br />

associated with a wide range <strong>of</strong> pollutants, this is quite surprising. At one point in the<br />

study. The authors note:<br />

950<br />

29/09/09<br />

The remaining air pollutants are: HCl/HF, 1,1-Dichloroethane, Chloroethane,<br />

Chlorothene, Chlorobenzene, Tertrachloroethene, Arsenic, Benzene,<br />

Cadmium, Nickel, Mercury, Dioxins and Furans, Polychlorinated Biphenyls.<br />

Valuation studies for these air pollutants are limited to their health impacts,<br />

i.e. cancer and deaths brought forward, as identified in the scientific study<br />

and covered in Section 4.1. Thus, to determine per kg estimates per<br />

pollutant, these health impacts need to be multiplied by the number <strong>of</strong> cancer<br />

cases and deaths brought forward per kg <strong>of</strong> pollutant. 1167<br />

The statement is never really followed up, either in the externalities report, or the<br />

‘combining’ report <strong>of</strong> HM C&E. Evidently, to the extent that many emissions which<br />

may be <strong>of</strong> significance are effectively attributed a zero damage cost, then other things<br />

being equal, the externalities from both landfill and incineration are likely to be<br />

different from their actual value. Whether they should be higher or lower depends<br />

upon the balance <strong>of</strong> direct impacts and the <strong>of</strong>fsets associated with avoided pollution.<br />

It is, perhaps, worth commenting in this context that a more recent Norwegian study<br />

suggested that pollutants such as chromium, manganese (two pollutants not<br />

mentioned in the italicized paragraph above) and dioxins account for up to 85-95% <strong>of</strong><br />

the total socioeconomic costs <strong>of</strong> waste incineration. 1168<br />

61.3.2.2 Conservative Estimation <strong>of</strong> Damages <strong>of</strong> Pollutants Assessed<br />

Second, the valuation <strong>of</strong> the damages associated with the individual pollutants is at<br />

variance with the estimates being derived from other sources. In itself, this is not<br />

surprising, and indeed, it is positive to the extent that the study seeks to derive<br />

project-relevant estimates. Rather, it is difficult to find two studies that give identical<br />

results.<br />

In Europe, successive attempts have been made in the context <strong>of</strong> the ExternE<br />

programme, the development <strong>of</strong> the Benefits Table (BeTa) database, and most<br />

recently, damage cost estimates from the Clean Air for Europe (CAFÉ) programme, to<br />

1167 Enviros and EFTEC (2004) Valuation Of The External Costs And Benefits To Health And<br />

Environment Of <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options Final Report for Defra, December 2004.<br />

1168 ECON, Senter for økonomisk analyse (Centre for Economic Analysis) (2000) Miljøkostnader ved<br />

avfallsbehandling, ECON-report 85/00. The study is one <strong>of</strong> a number which were not considered in the<br />

review <strong>of</strong> external costs <strong>of</strong> waste management undertaken in the context <strong>of</strong> the health Effects work,<br />

including a number undertaken for the European Commission.


arrive at a ‘best estimate’ <strong>of</strong> the damages associated with the pollutants being<br />

examined. 1169<br />

Given that knowledge <strong>of</strong> the health effects <strong>of</strong> various pollutants is still developing,<br />

and that some methodological issues are unresolved in the approaches to valuation,<br />

it is to be expected that estimates will vary across studies. However, the values<br />

derived for use in the HM C&E study are almost all lower than those derived for the<br />

UK in the CAFÉ study. Indeed, only for PM does the high end <strong>of</strong> the range used in the<br />

body <strong>of</strong> work we are discussing overlap with any part <strong>of</strong> the range deemed<br />

appropriate from the UK-based modelling under CAFÉ.<br />

The Enviros and EFTEC study adopts a sophisticated modelling approach to<br />

understand the exposure arising from different sources <strong>of</strong> emissions but adopts<br />

conservative – possibly outdated - estimates <strong>of</strong> the impacts <strong>of</strong> the pollutants. As<br />

pointed out above, the analysis is doubly conservative since it concentrates on only a<br />

small range <strong>of</strong> pollutants.<br />

The estimates are considered conservative partly because a view from COMEAP - put<br />

forward in 1998 – suggested that several impacts should not be valued because<br />

‘accurate’ dose response functions could not be agreed upon. The values in this<br />

report, therefore, omit a range <strong>of</strong> health effects typically captured in EU studies, such<br />

as:<br />

951<br />

1. Congestive heart failure<br />

2. Restricted activity days<br />

3. Bronchodilator use<br />

4. Cough<br />

5. Lower respiratory symptoms –n children<br />

6. Cerebrovascular hospital admission<br />

7. Chronic bronchitis<br />

8. Chronic cough<br />

9. Asthma attack<br />

10. Minor restricted activity day<br />

For comparison, the unit damage costs derived from three studies are given in Table<br />

61-2.<br />

1169 See European Commission (1998) DGXII (JOULE Programme) Externalities <strong>of</strong> Energy, ExternE<br />

Project, Report Number 10, National Implementation. Edited by CIEMAT. Report available from<br />

European Commission DG Research; M. Holland and P. Watkiss (2002) Benefits Table Database:<br />

Estimates <strong>of</strong> the Marginal External Costs <strong>of</strong> Air Pollution in Europe, Database Prepared for European<br />

Commission DG Environment; AEAT Environment (2005) Damages per tonne Emission <strong>of</strong> PM2.5, NH3,<br />

SO2, NOx and VOCs from Each EU25 Member State (excluding Cyprus) and Surrounding Seas, Report<br />

to DG Environment <strong>of</strong> the European Commission, March 2005.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 61-2: Unit Damage Costs Used / Derived in Different Studies (£/tonne)<br />

952<br />

Pollutant Pollutant<br />

Pollutant<br />

29/09/09<br />

CSERGE CSERGE et et al<br />

1993 1993<br />

1993<br />

Enviros Enviros and and EFTEC<br />

EFTEC<br />

(2004) (2004)<br />

(2004)<br />

PM (landfill) 7,650 161 1,025<br />

PM<br />

(incineration)<br />

EU EU-CAFÉ EU CAFÉ<br />

(2005) (2005)<br />

(2005)<br />

Low High Low High<br />

7,650 6,119 39,425<br />

24,667 73,333<br />

SOx 643 2,941 4,400 12,667<br />

NOx 628 154 977 2,600 6,667<br />

VOCs 263 665 759 2207<br />

CO2 1.1-8.5 9.5 38 n/a n/a<br />

CH4 31-139 158 630 n/a n/a<br />

Sources: CSERGE, Warren Spring Laboratory and EFTEL (1993) Externalities from Landfill and<br />

Incineration, London: HMSO: Enviros and EFTEC (2004) Valuation Of The External Costs And Benefits<br />

To Health And Environment Of <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options Final Report for Defra, December 2004:<br />

AEAT Environment (2005) Damages per tonne Emission <strong>of</strong> PM2.5, NH3, SO2, NOx and VOCs from Each<br />

EU25 Member State (excluding Cyprus) and Surrounding Seas, Report to DG Environment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European Commission, March 2005. 1170<br />

61.3.2.3 Key Results<br />

The report from HM C&E derived, from the Enviros et al study and the Enviros and<br />

CSERGE study, values for the externalities from landfills and incineration. Results for<br />

what is termed the Central High scenario are given in Table 61-3.<br />

Taking the results at face value, then as Table 61-3 shows, the effect <strong>of</strong> using<br />

relatively low unit damage costs for non-GHGs is to render nothing important other<br />

1170 The interested reader is referred to the CAFÉ website and to the reports present there<br />

(http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/air/cafe/). It should be noted that independently <strong>of</strong> CAFÉ,<br />

the Danish institute, NERI, has come up with Danish values for damages associated with PM, NOx and<br />

SOx. In densely populated areas (towns with more than 500,000 inhabitants), they estimate damages<br />

from PM to be as high as £193,000 per tonne and for SOx, £86,667 per tonne. The figure for NOx – at<br />

£7,333 per tonne – is consistent with the higher end <strong>of</strong> the CAFÉ range (see M. Skou Andersen et al<br />

(2004) Sundhedseffekter af Luftforurening – Beregningspriser, DMU Report No. 507, Copenhagen:<br />

Danmarks Miljøundersøgelser). NERI also modelled the impact <strong>of</strong> dioxin emissions from incinerators<br />

(see D. Jensen and N. Dengsoe (2004) Værdisætning af skadesomkostninger ved affaldsforbrænding -<br />

en analyse af dioxiners skadelige effekter og et egneeksempel på disse effekters<br />

samfundsøkonomiske omkostninger, TemaNord 2004:518, Copenhagen, Nordic Ministry).


than greenhouse gases. This is hardly pr<strong>of</strong>ound (rather, it is tautological). Table 61-2<br />

shows that the unit damage costs for the non-GHG pollutants changed little between<br />

the CSERGE study and the Enviros and EFTEC study. The damage costs for GHGs, on<br />

the other hand, have moved significantly upwards.<br />

Table 61-3: Externalities as reported by HM C&E for Central High Scenario<br />

Externality Externality<br />

Externality<br />

953<br />

Incineration Incineration Incineration with<br />

with<br />

Energy Energy Recovery<br />

Recovery<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Landfill Landfill (medium) (medium) (medium) –<br />

Gas Gas Flared<br />

Flared<br />

Landfi Landfill Landfi ll (medium) – Gas<br />

Gas<br />

Used Used Used to to to Generate Generate<br />

Generate<br />

Electricity<br />

Electricity<br />

Costs -£19.11 -£9.83 -£12.04<br />

<strong>of</strong> which:<br />

CO2 -£19.09 -£3.82 -£5.73<br />

CH4 -£0.01 -£5.99 -£6.30<br />

VOCs -£0.00 -£0.00 -£0.00<br />

SO2 -£0.01 -£0.02 -£0.01<br />

Health -£0.01 -£0.00 -£0.00<br />

Benefits £6.16 n/a -£2.15<br />

Net Costs -£12.95 -£9.83 -£9.89<br />

Source: HM Customs & Excise (2004) Combining the Government’s Two Heath and Environment<br />

Studies to Calculate Estimates for the External Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfill and Incineration, December 2004.<br />

Notwithstanding the importance <strong>of</strong> GHGs, the presumption that ‘only GHGs matter’<br />

would suggest that there were no serious impacts arising from emissions associated<br />

with the incineration or landfilling <strong>of</strong> household waste stream. If this were the case,<br />

then this would be the first study, to our knowledge, to have arrived at such a<br />

conclusion (since, as discussed above, most studies have steadily expanded their<br />

scope in terms <strong>of</strong> emissions, and most have taken on board a general drift towards<br />

higher, not lower, unit damage costs). 1171 It might be tempting, on the basis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

results <strong>of</strong> this study, to simply concentrate on GHGs and ignore all other emissions<br />

when considering waste management options.<br />

Interrogating these figures and their provenance, it is very difficult to reproduce the<br />

same numbers. The air pollution effects appear to have been miscalculated. In the<br />

1171 The report on the damage costs produced under CAFÉ actually compares the values obtained with<br />

those derived in earlier European work to feed into the BeTa database. Higher end results from the<br />

CAFÉ work are higher than those obtained under the BeTa work by a factor <strong>of</strong> 2.7 for NOx, 8.7 for<br />

PM2.5, 3.9 for SO2 and 1.4 for VOCs.


central high scenario, the effects from SOx, NOx, VOCs and PM, even using the<br />

relatively conservative damage costs, are around £3.19 per tonne for incineration<br />

(319 times what is stated in the report) and £0.83 and £0.35 for the two landfill<br />

scenarios.<br />

By way <strong>of</strong> comparison, if the same emissions data is used, but one uses the high end<br />

estimates from the CAFÉ work, the externalities associated with the same pollutants<br />

are in excess <strong>of</strong> £15.00 per tonne for incineration, and around £6.00 per tonne for<br />

landfill with flaring. The differential is particularly great for NOx. In the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

studies reviewed by the main author <strong>of</strong> this study, NOx-related externalities have been<br />

significant contributors to the non-GHG externalities associated with incineration. The<br />

Enviros and EFTEC report effectively reduces their significance by assigning what<br />

appears to be an extremely low unit damage cost for NOx. The incorrect calculation in<br />

the HM Customs & Excise work exacerbates this. 1172<br />

61.3.3 Dijkgraaf & Vollebergh<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> a larger report by the Copenhagen based Environmental Assessment<br />

Institute, Dijkgraaf and Vollebergh ask whether available social cost-benefit<br />

evaluations <strong>of</strong> waste disposal provide support for the strict application <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

hierarchy. 1173 Of studies reviewed, two found incineration to be preferable to landfill<br />

from a social cost perspective, in support <strong>of</strong> the EU hierarchy. However, three other<br />

studies find that landfilling is the best option.<br />

The report also refers to an earlier study by the same authors. 1174 This detailed the<br />

findings in terms <strong>of</strong> private, environmental and total social costs arising from<br />

landfilling and incineration. This multiplied the net private and environmental costs<br />

per tonne <strong>of</strong> each treatment option in each <strong>of</strong> the EU-15 countries by total municipal<br />

waste arisings for that country. While total environmental costs for landfill are shown<br />

to be higher, the private costs <strong>of</strong> incineration are much more significant, with the<br />

overall result that the social costs <strong>of</strong> incineration are greater than those for landfill.<br />

These results are shown in Table 61-4.<br />

The authors quite rightly add a number <strong>of</strong> qualifications that must be borne in mind<br />

when interpreting these results, notably, the extent to which methane is used as a<br />

source <strong>of</strong> energy generation. This can have a great influence on the relative social<br />

costs <strong>of</strong> landfilling versus incineration. 1175 This is due not only to savings in energy<br />

1172 The Enviros and EFTEC report reviews ten secondary studies which provide valuation data for NOx.<br />

Only one has used a figure for NOx which is lower than the ‘high’ value derived in the context <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Enviros and EFTEC study. That study was carried out in 1995. All the others that were reviewed have<br />

been conducted more recently.<br />

1173 E. Dijkgraaf and H. Vollebergh (2005) Literature review <strong>of</strong> social costs and benefits <strong>of</strong> waste<br />

disposal and recycling, in EAI (2005) Rethinking the <strong>Waste</strong> Hierachy, EAI: Copenhagen, pp. 80-98.<br />

1174 E. Dijkgraaf and H. Vollebergh (2004) Burn or bury? A social cost comparison <strong>of</strong> final waste<br />

disposal methods, Ecological Economics, 50, pp.233-247.<br />

1175 E. Dijkgraaf and H. Vollebergh (2004) Burn or bury? A social cost comparison <strong>of</strong> final waste<br />

disposal methods, Ecological Economics, 50, pp.233-247;<br />

954<br />

29/09/09


production, but mainly the much lower emissions to air if methane is collected and<br />

used as an energy source.<br />

Table 61-4: Social Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfilling versus Incineration (million euros)<br />

955<br />

Total Total<br />

Total<br />

waste waste<br />

waste<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Costs Costs if if all all waste waste is is landfilled landfilled landfilled Co Costs Co sts if all waste is incinerated<br />

(M<br />

(M<br />

tonnes) tonnes) tonnes)<br />

Private Environmental Environmental Social Social Social Private Private Environmental Environmental Social<br />

Social<br />

Belgium 3 112 69 181 245 55 300<br />

Denmark 3 108 66 174 237 53 290<br />

Germany 25 901 554 1455 1977 442 2419<br />

Finland 2 75 46 121 164 37 201<br />

France 24 857 527 1385 1881 420 2301<br />

Greece 5 192 118 309 420 94 514<br />

Ireland 2 67 41 108 146 33 179<br />

Italy 29 1036 637 1672 2273 507 2780<br />

Luxembourg 0 5 3 8 10 2 13<br />

Netherlands 5 173 106 280 380 85 465<br />

Austria 2 89 54 143 194 43 238<br />

Portugal 5 181 111 292 396 88 485<br />

Spain 20 712 438 1150 1563 349 1912<br />

UK 30 1067 656 1724 2342 523 2866<br />

Sweden 4 129 79 208 283 63 346<br />

Total EU 158 5702 3507 9209 12514 2794 15308<br />

Source: Dijkgraaf, E., and H. Vollebergh (2004)<br />

In addition, the benefits <strong>of</strong> incineration due to displaced emissions from electricity<br />

generating plant can sometimes be overstated. It is therefore important to know the<br />

reference energy generation technology that is assumed to be displaced. Some<br />

studies assume this to be a coal fired plant. Others assume gas-fired plants, which<br />

result in a much lower saving in emissions from incineration.<br />

61.3.4 COWI<br />

This report, dating from 2000, presented economic valuation estimates for<br />

externalities associated with landfill disposal and incineration <strong>of</strong> waste. 1176 Further to<br />

this they provide a series <strong>of</strong> example cost calculations under different assumptions,<br />

the aim being to quantify the main externalities according to typical scenarios for<br />

disposal and incineration.<br />

Included are the following external cost components<br />

� greenhouse gases;<br />

1176 COWI (2000) External Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfill and Incineration, Final Report to the European Commission.


956<br />

� conventional air pollutants and some airborne toxic substances;<br />

� leachate; and<br />

� disamenity effects.<br />

Importantly, the examples include external benefits in the form <strong>of</strong> displaced<br />

emissions from energy recovery.<br />

Three examples were defined for incineration, reflecting different technological<br />

standards and levels <strong>of</strong> energy recovery.<br />

� I1. The incineration plant fulfils the (then proposed) directive on incineration <strong>of</strong><br />

waste (Common Position (2000/C 25/02)). Energy recovered will generate<br />

electricity and heat (CHP). The percentage recovery is assumed to be 83%.<br />

� I2. The incineration plant fulfils the (then existing) directive on incineration <strong>of</strong><br />

waste (89/369/EEC). Energy recovered will generate electricity only. The<br />

percentage recovery is assumed to be 25%.<br />

� The incineration plant does not fulfil the (then existing) directive. The flue gas<br />

cleaning technology is an electrostatic precipitator. There is no energy<br />

recovery.<br />

Two examples were defined for landfill disposal <strong>of</strong> waste, reflecting different<br />

technological standards and levels <strong>of</strong> energy recovery.<br />

� L1. The landfill is a modern containment landfill that fulfils the demands <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Landfill Directive. 1177 The landfill has a leachate collection and treatment<br />

system. Further the landfill gas is collected to generate electricity and heat<br />

(CHP).<br />

� L2. The landfill is an old site without a liner and landfill gas is not collected.<br />

The resulting external costs are shown in Table 61-5.<br />

1177 Council Directive 99/31/EC.<br />

29/09/09


Table 61-5: Summary <strong>of</strong> externality costs for incineration and landfill scenarios<br />

(€/tonne)<br />

957<br />

Impact Impact Impact I1 I1 I2 I2 I3 I3 L1 L1 L2 L2<br />

Global<br />

warming<br />

Damage<br />

from air<br />

pollution<br />

Damage<br />

from<br />

leachate<br />

Disamenity<br />

Total<br />

Total<br />

external<br />

external<br />

costs<br />

costs<br />

Pollution<br />

displacement<br />

Net Net external<br />

external<br />

costs<br />

costs<br />

Source: COWI, 2000<br />

0.8<br />

(0.5 - 1.0)<br />

20<br />

(5 - 27)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

0<br />

(0 – 0.3)<br />

8<br />

(4 - 14)<br />

28<br />

(10 (10 (10 – 43)<br />

43)<br />

-71<br />

(-115 - -19)<br />

-43 43<br />

(-72 72 - -9) 9)<br />

0.8<br />

(0.5 - 1.0)<br />

50<br />

(15 - 72)<br />

0<br />

(0 – 0.3)<br />

8<br />

(4 - 14)<br />

58<br />

(20 (20 – 88)<br />

88)<br />

-21<br />

(-29 - -4)<br />

37 37<br />

(19 (19 – 84)<br />

84)<br />

0.8<br />

(0.5 - 1.0)<br />

69<br />

(20 – 108)<br />

0<br />

(0 – 0.3)<br />

8<br />

( 4 - 14)<br />

77<br />

(25 (25 – 124)<br />

124)<br />

0<br />

(-)<br />

77<br />

(25 (25 (25 – 124)<br />

124)<br />

5<br />

(1 – 14)<br />

0.1<br />

(0.02 –<br />

0.2)<br />

0<br />

(0 – 1)<br />

10<br />

(6 – 19)<br />

15 15<br />

(7 – 34)<br />

34)<br />

-4<br />

(-10 - -1)<br />

11 11<br />

(6 – 24)<br />

24)<br />

8<br />

(2 – 23)<br />

0<br />

(-)<br />

1.5<br />

(1 – 2)<br />

10<br />

(6 – 19)<br />

20<br />

(9 – 44)<br />

44)<br />

0<br />

(-)<br />

20 20<br />

(9 – 44)<br />

44)<br />

Understanding the various assumptions underpinning these results is important.<br />

Where incineration produces electricity, the authors credit it with displacing emissions<br />

from a coal fired plant. The assumption that electricity from coal fired plant is the<br />

marginal source has a large impact on the analysis. If gas, arguably a more likely<br />

marginal generation source, was assumed to be displaced, the credited greenhouse<br />

gas emissions would be significantly reduced. Moreover, the study also includes<br />

emissions from mining and transport <strong>of</strong> the coal, while not accounting for transport<br />

emissions associated with waste delivered to the incinerator. This somewhat<br />

overstates the benefits <strong>of</strong> displaced energy generation. The assumed conversion<br />

efficiencies could also be argued to be rather high.<br />

The authors undertake sensitivity analysis using oil as the displaced fuel for electricity<br />

generation. For I1, this roughly halves the pollution displacement, resulting in a net<br />

external benefit <strong>of</strong> €9/tonne waste incinerated instead <strong>of</strong> the benefit <strong>of</strong> €43/tonne<br />

waste incinerated with coal as the displaced source. Displacing gas, with a lower


carbon intensity, would have brought the external costs more in line with those <strong>of</strong> the<br />

better performing landfill, L1.<br />

In the nine years since the report was written, the general European trend has been<br />

towards an increase in unit damage costs associated with both greenhouse gas and<br />

non-greenhouse gas emissions. Against this backdrop, the trend in carbon intensity <strong>of</strong><br />

electricity generation in Europe has been downwards, and is expected to drop even<br />

more significantly over coming decades. In interpreting these results, factors such as<br />

these must be borne in mind. What this study would appear to suggest is that, again,<br />

contrary to what is assumed in the waste hierarchy, landfill is not always<br />

unequivocally worse than incineration.<br />

61.3.5 Eunomia and Tobin Reports for Greenstar, 2007 and 2008<br />

The first <strong>of</strong> these reports, looking at waste policy, planning and regulation in Ireland<br />

presented damage cost estimates for landfill and incineration as shown in Table<br />

61-6. 1178 ‘High’ and ‘low’ in the column headings refer to the unit damage cost<br />

estimates applied.<br />

Table 61-6: Externalities from Landfill and Incineration (€/tonne)<br />

Direct emissions<br />

non-GHG related<br />

Direct emissions<br />

GHG related<br />

Total Total Direct<br />

Direct<br />

Emissions<br />

Emissions<br />

958<br />

29/09/09<br />

Incineration,<br />

Incineration,<br />

Low<br />

Low<br />

Incineration,<br />

Incineration,<br />

High<br />

High<br />

Landfill Landfill (75% (75%<br />

(75%<br />

engine, engine, 25%<br />

25%<br />

flaring), flaring), Low Low<br />

Low<br />

Landfill Landfill (75% (75%<br />

(75%<br />

engine, engine, 25%<br />

25%<br />

flaring), flaring), High<br />

High<br />

€6.86 €19.80 €2.92 €8.46<br />

€17.73 €17.73 €12.76 €12.76<br />

€24 24 24.59 24 59 59 €37 37 37.53 37 53 53 €15 15 15.68 15 68 68 €21 21 21.22 21 22 22<br />

Offsets GHG related - €4.78 - €4.78 - €1.09 - €1.09<br />

Offsets non-GHG - €3.11 - €8.92 - €0.71 - €2.03<br />

Total Total Off Offsets Off sets - €7.89 89 - €13 13 13.70 13<br />

- €1.80 80 - €3.12 12<br />

Net Net Net Environmental<br />

Environmental<br />

Damages<br />

Damages<br />

Source: Eunomia and Tobin, 2007<br />

€16 16 16.71 16 71 €23 €23.8 €23 €23.8<br />

.84 .8 €13 13 13.89 13 89 €18 18 18.11 18 11<br />

1178 Eunomia and Tobin (2007) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, Planning and Regulation in Ireland, Final Report for<br />

Greenstar, Dublin, Ireland.


The second report, on the potential role <strong>of</strong> MBT in meeting Ireland’s waste targets,<br />

presented damage cost estimates for landfill, incineration, and MBT as shown in<br />

Table 61-7. 1179<br />

Table 61-7: Externalities from Landfill, Incineration and MBT (€/tonne)<br />

959<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Landfill Landfill Landfill Incineration<br />

Incineration Incineration MBT MBT<br />

MBT<br />

Direct emissions non-GHG related €2.64 €23.51 €0.49<br />

Direct emissions GHG related €59.13 €28.71 €15.62<br />

Total Total Total Direct Direct Direct Emissions Emissions Emissions<br />

€61.78 €61.78 €52.22 €52.22 €52.22 €16.11 €16.11<br />

€16.11<br />

Offsets GHG related - €1.60 - €6.79 - €4.72<br />

Offsets non-GHG - €2.95 - €9.61 - €6.18<br />

Total Total Offsets Offsets<br />

- €4.55 €4.55 - €16.40 €16.40 - €10.90<br />

€10.90<br />

Net Net Net Environmenta<br />

Environmental Environmenta<br />

Environmental<br />

l Damages Damages €57.23 €57.23 €35.82 €35.82 €35.82 €5.22 €5.22<br />

€5.22<br />

Disamenity €4.25 €14.30 €9.28<br />

Total Total External External External Costs Costs<br />

€61.48 €61.48 €61.48 €50.12 €50.12 €50.12 €14.49 €14.49<br />

€14.49<br />

Source: Eunomia and Tobin, 2008<br />

The differences between these two reports give an interesting insight into the way<br />

that assumptions affect the end result <strong>of</strong> such studies.<br />

In the first report, the authors applied external cost estimates to emissions data from<br />

another study carried out in the UK. This was used because it was being widely<br />

quoted in Ireland (and the UK) as evidence <strong>of</strong> an absence <strong>of</strong> health effects from<br />

incineration. Where landfill is concerned, the figures for emissions are low, partly<br />

because gas capture rates from the landfill are assumed to be high in the study.<br />

For the second report, the authors used their own modelling, developed over a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> years. This incorporates LCA and CBA information, and permits the<br />

modelling <strong>of</strong> the impacts <strong>of</strong> time upon those emissions which do occur over an<br />

extended period <strong>of</strong> time. Typical LCA studies, as previously mentioned, do not permit<br />

this. A lower gas capture rate was also assumed for methane at the landfill.<br />

For incineration, the emissions were modelled ‘back’ to the input waste composition.<br />

Emissions are therefore based upon a full engineering assessment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

1179 Eunomia and Tobin (2008) Meeting Ireland’s <strong>Waste</strong> Targets: The role <strong>of</strong> MBT, Final Report for<br />

Greenstar, Dublin, Ireland.


composition <strong>of</strong> the waste and the implications <strong>of</strong> this for emissions, assuming a<br />

particular configuration <strong>of</strong> flue gas cleaning (as per the proposed Dublin incinerator).<br />

For the second report, only high-end unit damage costs were used, whereas for the<br />

first, low and high estimates were derived using different figures. Strictly speaking,<br />

the only comparison is between the high values in the first report and the values in<br />

the second. For incineration, disamenity accounts for a large proportion <strong>of</strong> this, while<br />

for the first report, disamenity figures were not included.<br />

For landfill, the change in assumptions regarding gas capture is the most important.<br />

(This remains an area where there is surprisingly little agreement as to what the<br />

correct figure should be).<br />

Again the outcomes <strong>of</strong> these two reports show that the ordering <strong>of</strong> the lower tiers <strong>of</strong><br />

the waste hierarchy is not always supported by a cost-benefit appraisal.<br />

61.3.5.1 A Note on Disamenity<br />

The EFTEC and Enviros study underpinning the HM C&E work reviewed some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

literature on disamenity. Cambridge Econometrics and EFTEC themselves carried out<br />

a major hedonic pricing study which estimated the disamenity associated with<br />

landfilling. 1180 This was based upon a hedonic pricing study, examining the effect <strong>of</strong><br />

proximity to landfills on house prices. The Enviros and EFTEC study updated the<br />

estimates from the previous study (inflating the estimates in line with house price<br />

inflation), giving a range for landfill disamenity <strong>of</strong> between £2.50 and £3.59 per<br />

tonne.<br />

However, the Eftec and Enviros study excluded disamenity impacts because it felt<br />

that the only relevant study concerning incineration – from the US – was not<br />

transferable to the UK context. Kiel and McClain looked at the effects on house prices<br />

over time from the pre-rumour stage, through to the rumour stage, the construction<br />

phase, the online phase, and later years <strong>of</strong> operation. 1181 They found that house<br />

prices were affected only once construction began and peaked in earlier years <strong>of</strong><br />

operation before falling back slightly. The effect was a reduction <strong>of</strong> the order 3% per<br />

mile in the vicinity <strong>of</strong> the incinerator.<br />

At one level, the decision not to use the study’s findings was understandable. It was,<br />

after all, carried out in the United States and the transferability <strong>of</strong> the results would<br />

be questionable. However, the reasoning given is interesting. It was noted<br />

960<br />

29/09/09<br />

‘When this [the disamenity from the incinerator] is compared to the average<br />

disamenity cost <strong>of</strong> landfill from the Defra study <strong>of</strong> between £551,000 to<br />

£789,000 when converted to £2003 prices using house price index changes,<br />

the results <strong>of</strong> Kiel and McClain seem disproportionately large. For this, and<br />

1180 Cambridge Econometrics in association with EFTEC and WRc (2003) A Study to Estimate the<br />

Disamenity Costs <strong>of</strong> Landfill in Great Britain, London:Defra, February 2003.<br />

1181 K.A. Kiel and K.T. McClain (1995) House Prices during Siting Decision Stages: The Case <strong>of</strong> an<br />

Incinerator from Rumour through Operation. Journal <strong>of</strong> Environmental Economics and <strong>Management</strong><br />

28, 241-255.


961<br />

also given the fact that the study is from the US, this estimate is not<br />

recommended for use in the UK context’.<br />

This is very different to the view taken in a recent Dutch study: 1182<br />

Given these findings, we assume that the disamenity effects differ between<br />

landfilling and incineration. First, the reduction in house prices seems to be<br />

more pronounced with incineration. This may be due to the fact that<br />

incineration is mainly disliked because <strong>of</strong> the perception <strong>of</strong> air pollution. In the<br />

Netherlands, since the negative publicity <strong>of</strong> the emissions <strong>of</strong> the highly toxic<br />

dioxins in the early 1990s, people are more reluctant to live near an<br />

incinerator. Even if the legal standards are met, the fear will not disappear<br />

immediately. Second, due to the importance <strong>of</strong> air emissions and the height <strong>of</strong><br />

the stack, the impact area <strong>of</strong> an incinerator is significantly larger than the<br />

area affected by a landfill site. Therefore, the area <strong>of</strong> affected houses around<br />

the landfill site is limited to a buffer <strong>of</strong> 1 kilometre around the site. The impact<br />

area <strong>of</strong> incinerators in the Netherlands is assumed to reach as far as 5<br />

kilometres from the actual site.<br />

The study estimated minimum and maximum values for disamenity <strong>of</strong> €9.1-9.9 per<br />

tonne (approx £6.50-7.00 per tonne).<br />

A recent French study carried out a contingent valuation study to assess<br />

disamenity. 1183 The reported results were estimated at €4.3/tonne (a range <strong>of</strong> €3.7-<br />

4.9 per tonne). The study suggested that these levels were likely to include some<br />

estimate (from residents) <strong>of</strong> the impacts <strong>of</strong> air pollution. Consequently, it hinted that<br />

these might be high estimates. The relatively low value in the French study may be<br />

explained by the fact that the incinerator chosen for the study was in an area <strong>of</strong><br />

relatively low population density (3km from a city <strong>of</strong> 50,000 inhabitants), dealing with<br />

85,000 tonnes from 52 communes. As such, the disamenity per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste might<br />

be suppressed by the reduced density <strong>of</strong> housing stock affected by the facility.<br />

Another French study is worth reporting. Rabl et al intended to carry out a contingent<br />

valuation study in France, however, these plans did not materialise:<br />

Initial plans <strong>of</strong> our research project had been to carry out a contingent<br />

valuation in France. However, at none <strong>of</strong> the sites suitable for a case study<br />

were the authorities willing to let us survey the opinions <strong>of</strong> the population. The<br />

projects were too controversial, and the authorities were afraid <strong>of</strong> anything<br />

they perceived as potential outside interference. 1184<br />

1182 H. Bartelings, P. van Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk<br />

(2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong> Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM,<br />

November 24, 2005.<br />

1183 O. Arnold and S. Terra (2006) Consentement Local a Payer et Localisation d’un Incinerateur, Serie-<br />

Etudes 05-E10, Ministere de l’Ecologie et du Developpement Durable.<br />

1184 A. Rabl et al (1999) Impact Assessment and Authorization Procedure for Installations with Major<br />

Environmental Risks, Contract ENV4-CT96-0236, DG XII European Commission, July 1999.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The authors went on to explore attitudes <strong>of</strong> households to different cost and benefit<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>iles in an area where facilities were still being discussed.<br />

In our view, it would be reasonable to expect significant disamenity from incinerators<br />

as measured through hedonic pricing for the simple reason that the density <strong>of</strong><br />

housing stock is likely to be greater around incinerators than around landfills. Quite<br />

how the disamenity effects <strong>of</strong> incineration, as measured through contingent valuation<br />

approaches, would compare with landfill is still unclear (and likely to vary with<br />

location). To the extent that population densities are important, the fact that<br />

incinerators are usually in urban or peri-urban locations would suggest that the<br />

disamenity would be larger (simply because more households would be affected). On<br />

the other hand, we have only limited knowledge from studies seeking to elicit the<br />

disamenity associated with municipal waste incineration so do not know the speed at<br />

which the disamenity experienced falls with distance (and whether it varies with<br />

capacity, and if so how?). Brisson and Pearce suggest 4 miles as the domain <strong>of</strong><br />

influence for landfills. It could be that this is less in the case <strong>of</strong> incinerators (though<br />

the Dutch study cited above assumed it was 5km). 1185<br />

COWI, in work for the European Commission, used the meta-analysis <strong>of</strong> Pearce and<br />

Brisson, relating house price reductions to proximity to a landfill, and assumed the<br />

same relationship applied to houses located near incinerators. 1186 COWI used a<br />

population density around the typical incinerator <strong>of</strong> 120 per square mile. Yet<br />

incinerators are rarely located in such sparsely populated areas. Eunomia et al<br />

suggested that the population densities are typically an order <strong>of</strong> magnitude larger.<br />

They suggested if COWI had used a figure <strong>of</strong> 1,200 households per square mile (469<br />

per square kilometre), the values derived for a 200,000 tonne site, with the annual<br />

disamenity being set at 8% <strong>of</strong> the total, is around €75 per tonne. On the basis <strong>of</strong> this,<br />

they suggested that the importance <strong>of</strong> the housing density should not be underestimated<br />

in the modelling <strong>of</strong> incinerator-related disamenity, and that further work<br />

was urgently needed in this area. 1187<br />

It is clear that both the COWI and Eunomia studies derived figures which were<br />

dependent upon the transferability <strong>of</strong> a relationship derived for landfills to the<br />

incinerator context. Neither study used the disamenity estimate derived in their<br />

ultimate analysis. It seems possible, however, that disamenity values could be<br />

considerable for these facilities.<br />

To our knowledge, no studies <strong>of</strong> disamenity have been carried out at other waste<br />

treatment facilities (than landfill and incineration)<br />

1185 Brisson, Inger and David Pearce (1995) Benefits Transfer for Disamenity from <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal,<br />

CSERGE Working Paper WM 95-06, London: CSERGE.<br />

1186 COWI (2000) A Study on the Economic Valuation <strong>of</strong> Environmental Externalities from Landfill<br />

Disposal and Incineration <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>. Final Report to DG Environment, the European Commission,<br />

August 2000.<br />

1187 Eunomia Research & Consulting, Scuola Agraria del Parco di Monza, HDRA Consultants, ZREU and<br />

LDK ECO on behalf <strong>of</strong> ECOTEC Research & Consulting (2002) Economic Analysis <strong>of</strong> Options for<br />

Managing Biodegradable Municipal <strong>Waste</strong>, Final Report to the European Commission.<br />

962<br />

29/09/09


61.4 Concluding Remarks on the Literature<br />

A number <strong>of</strong> points have arisen from the studies reviewed.<br />

1. Estimates <strong>of</strong> the unit damage costs for individual pollutants appear to increasing<br />

over time. Although there is still some dispute over which methodological<br />

approach is more valid (VSL or VOLY), the suggestion would be that a forward<br />

looking appraisal <strong>of</strong> pollution might tend towards the use <strong>of</strong> damage costs at the<br />

higher, rather than the lower end <strong>of</strong> existing ranges;<br />

2. In addition, the range <strong>of</strong> pollutants to which damage costs are attributed is<br />

likewise increasing.<br />

3. The unit damage costs for greenhouse gas pollutants are also tending to increase<br />

over time;<br />

4. The pressure to deal with climate change is leading to a lower carbon intensity<br />

associated with electricity generation, and this trend is expected to continue.<br />

Consequently the benefits associated with energy generated from waste are likely<br />

to decline over time.<br />

5. Landfill may sometimes have greater external costs than incineration, but this is<br />

not always the case. A critical assumption is the capture rate for gas assumed at<br />

the landfill, whilst the assumption concerning the avoided source <strong>of</strong> energy is also<br />

critical;<br />

6. Very few studies have looked at MBT processes, and therefore very few have<br />

looked at the impacts <strong>of</strong> landfilling pre-treated/stabilised waste;<br />

7. Given points 1 & 2, and with pre-treatment becoming more widespread, there is<br />

no reason to believe landfilling <strong>of</strong> pre-treated waste is necessarily worse than<br />

incineration from an environmental perspective, at least given the boundaries<br />

within which valuation studies are currently forced to work;<br />

8. Disamenity may also be significant for residual (and other) waste treatment<br />

plants.<br />

To conclude, all these points suggest that especially at the bottom <strong>of</strong> the waste<br />

hierarchy, the ordering appears to be far from unequivocal from an environmental<br />

point <strong>of</strong> view. It should be re-emphasised that few CBAs manage to capture all<br />

possible effects, and it is not entirely clear that those that are not captured would, if<br />

included, have only a small impact on the outcomes.<br />

963<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


62.0 Life-cycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Treatment Technologies<br />

This section carries out a life cycle assessment <strong>of</strong> a range <strong>of</strong> residual waste treatment<br />

technologies, using the Environment Agency’s tool WRATE. The assessment is<br />

described in Section 62.1. Limitations <strong>of</strong> the LCA approach in general (as exemplified<br />

by the WRATE analysis) are described in Section 62.2.<br />

62.1 Life-cycle Assessment Using WRATE<br />

A recently published report produced by Fehily Timoney & Company (FTC), Veolia and<br />

Ramboll sought to investigate the role that the Mechanical Biological Treatment <strong>of</strong><br />

waste might play within the Irish waste management sector. 1188 Their report included<br />

an environmental impact appraisal which used the life-cycle tool WRATE to assess<br />

these impacts. Their appraisal indicated that the thermal treatment scenario which<br />

included the recovery <strong>of</strong> both heat and electricity performed the best against the six<br />

assessment criteria considered within WRATE’s default assessment method.<br />

However, their analysis also briefly considered results obtained using the full range <strong>of</strong><br />

MBT processes included within the s<strong>of</strong>tware. The latter assessment concluded that<br />

there was considerable relative variability between the different MBT systems.<br />

The approach taken within the current appraisal is to examine in more detail the<br />

variation seen in the results <strong>of</strong> the impact assessments indicated by WRATE for a<br />

range <strong>of</strong> MBT and incineration options. In addition, Eunomia holds an Expert License<br />

for the s<strong>of</strong>tware, which provides additional functionality with regard to analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

impacts at each <strong>of</strong> the process stages. This enables the identification <strong>of</strong> specific<br />

pollutants or chemicals causing the impact at each stage <strong>of</strong> the treatment process,<br />

within each <strong>of</strong> the impact assessments.<br />

Our modelling uses the default impact assessment methods included within the<br />

model. We have made the following core assumptions across all treatments<br />

considered within the appraisal:<br />

964<br />

� We have used the residual waste composition data recently produced by RPS<br />

for the EPA; 1189<br />

� The baseline fuel mix is based on the 2007 mix for Ireland; we have separately<br />

defined the marginal electricity source as a modern combined-cycle gas<br />

turbine (CCGT, reflecting the carbon intensity <strong>of</strong> the new build <strong>of</strong> electricity<br />

generation sources). Whilst the former is used when calculating impacts<br />

1188 Fehily Timoney & Company / Veolia Environmental Services / Ramboll (2008) Critical Analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

the Potential for Mechanical Biological Treatment for Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Volume 2, Research<br />

Report, Report for the Environmental Protection Agency, September 2008.<br />

1189 RPS (2009) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Characterisation Surveys 2008, Report for the EPA, March 2009.<br />

29/09/09


965<br />

associated with fuel used within facilities, the latter is used to determine<br />

avoided emissions resulting from energy generated by facilities. 1190<br />

WRATE’s default assumption is that heat generation <strong>of</strong>fsets use <strong>of</strong> gas-fuelled heat<br />

generation. We have retained this assumption.<br />

Our assessment is carried out on the basis <strong>of</strong> impacts associated with 1 tonne <strong>of</strong><br />

residual waste sent to each treatment facility. The results presented in the following<br />

sections are not directly comparable to those produced by the FTC analysis, as the<br />

latter also considered impacts associated with collection and recycling <strong>of</strong> 100,000<br />

tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste within each <strong>of</strong> their four scenarios.<br />

Our analysis considers the performance <strong>of</strong> the following thermal treatment facilities<br />

against key WRATE criteria:<br />

� Chineham incinerator, generating electricity only (Incin Elec C in the graphs);<br />

� Dundee incinerator, generating electricity only (Incin Elec D);<br />

� Billingham incinerator, generating electricity only (Incin Elec B);<br />

� Coventry incinerator, generating electricity and heat (Incin CHP C);<br />

� Grimsby incinerator, generating electricity and heat (Incin CHP G).<br />

The WRATE model includes two categories <strong>of</strong> MBT process – the “generic” processes<br />

modelled using data obtained through literature published on MBT processes – and<br />

proprietary processes (e.g. the Ecodeco process) compiled using data provided by<br />

facility operators wherever possible. Whilst the FTC analysis considered only the two<br />

generic processes, we have included two additional facilities within the analysis that<br />

follows:<br />

� The Arrowbio Anaerobic Digestion-based MBT plant;<br />

� The Ecodeco MBT facility (producing an SRF which is sent to the Chineham<br />

incinerator, generating electricity only).<br />

In each case, the performance <strong>of</strong> the MBT and incineration facilities is compared to<br />

that <strong>of</strong> landfill.<br />

62.1.1 WRATE Impact Assessment<br />

The default impact assessment method within WRATE considers the performance <strong>of</strong><br />

technology options against the following criteria:<br />

1. Abiotic Resource Depletion<br />

2. Global Warming Potential<br />

3. Human Toxicity Potential<br />

1190 The baseline mix includes 22% Coal, 54% Gas and 11% Peat. See: Energy <strong>Policy</strong> Statistical<br />

Support Unit (2008) Energy in Ireland 1990 – 2007, Report for Sustainable Energy Ireland, December<br />

2008.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


kg kg antimony antimony eq.<br />

eq.<br />

966<br />

4. Freshwater Aquatic Eco-Toxicity<br />

5. Acidification<br />

6. Eutrophication<br />

These will be considered within each <strong>of</strong> the sections that follow.<br />

62.1.1.1 Abiotic Resource Depletion<br />

Abiotic Resource Depletion can be defined as the decreasing availability <strong>of</strong> natural,<br />

non-living, non renewable resources. Within the context <strong>of</strong> waste management this is<br />

likely to be related to the ability <strong>of</strong> treatment processes to generate energy, or to<br />

reduce the requirement for energy and raw material use through the recycling <strong>of</strong><br />

materials. The default assessment in WRATE considers these impacts in terms <strong>of</strong> kg<br />

antimony equivalent.<br />

The results presented in Figure 62-1 indicate that the best performer is the Arrowbio<br />

AD-based MBT facility. Landfill is the worst performing option against this assessment<br />

criterion, with the Dundee incinerator the second worst performer. However all<br />

options result in a negative value as each either generates energy or recycles some <strong>of</strong><br />

the input waste stream.<br />

Figure 62-1: Abiotic Resource Depletion (AD)<br />

0.00<br />

-0.50<br />

-1.00<br />

-1.50<br />

-2.00<br />

-2.50<br />

-3.00<br />

29/09/09<br />

Landfill Ecodeco<br />

MBT<br />

-0.46<br />

-1.67<br />

Generic<br />

Aero MBT<br />

-1.42<br />

Generic<br />

AD MBT<br />

-1.76<br />

AD<br />

Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

-2.84<br />

Incin Elec<br />

C<br />

-2.20<br />

Incin Elec<br />

D<br />

-1.08<br />

Incin Elec<br />

B<br />

-1.60<br />

Incin CHP<br />

C<br />

-2.00<br />

Incin CHP<br />

G<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> the impact is from avoidance <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> gas as a result <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

generation. Facilities also gain from the avoided oil use. The Arrowbio AD-based MBT<br />

plant performs best under the assessment owing to the relatively high levels <strong>of</strong><br />

material recycling assumed, alongside generation <strong>of</strong> energy through combustion <strong>of</strong><br />

biogas.<br />

-2.43


kg kg CO2 CO2 eq. eq.<br />

62.1.1.2 Global Warming Potential<br />

The Global Warming Potential is a measure <strong>of</strong> how much a given mass <strong>of</strong> greenhouse<br />

gas is estimated to contribute to Global Warming. The default impact assessment in<br />

WRATE considers impacts over 100 years, calculated in terms <strong>of</strong> CO2 equivalent<br />

emissions.<br />

The results presented in Figure 62-2 indicate that the Arrowbio AD-based MBT facility<br />

also performs well against this assessment criterion, due to avoided emissions<br />

resulting from a substantial amount <strong>of</strong> materials removed for recycling, along with<br />

emissions avoided as a result <strong>of</strong> the generation <strong>of</strong> energy from biogas. However, the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> MBT processes considered within WRATE do not fare well when assessed<br />

against the global warming impact assessment criterion. Our analysis indicates that<br />

the generic MBT facilities (along with the Dundee and Grimsby incinerators) perform<br />

worse than landfill in this case. This is clearly somewhat counter-intuitive and<br />

deserves explanation.<br />

Figure 62-2: Global Warming Potential (GWP100)<br />

350.00<br />

300.00<br />

250.00<br />

200.00<br />

150.00<br />

100.00<br />

50.00<br />

0.00<br />

-50.00<br />

967<br />

218.00<br />

202.00<br />

Landfill Ecodeco<br />

MBT<br />

321.00<br />

Generic<br />

Aero MBT<br />

269.00<br />

Generic<br />

AD MBT<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

-9.62 AD<br />

Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

144.00<br />

Incin Elec<br />

C<br />

293.00<br />

Incin Elec<br />

D<br />

200.00<br />

Incin Elec<br />

B<br />

88.60<br />

Incin CHP<br />

C<br />

247.00<br />

Incin CHP<br />

G<br />

The poor performance <strong>of</strong> the MBT facilities within WRATE largely results from the<br />

methodology used within the model to estimate emissions from landfill occurring from<br />

pre-treated wastes. The model assumes a proportion <strong>of</strong> the carbon is degraded within<br />

the biological part <strong>of</strong> the process and accounts for this in terms <strong>of</strong> the biogenic<br />

carbon emissions that are reported as an information item within its inventory <strong>of</strong><br />

emissions. 1191 However, when this material is subsequently landfilled, the resulting<br />

1191 CO2 emissions generated from biogenic carbon sources are not included within the total CO2<br />

emissions considered within the Global Warming Potential assessment criterion.


kg kg 1,4-dichlorobenzene 1,4-dichlorobenzene eq.<br />

eq.<br />

methane emissions – considered in terms <strong>of</strong> kg <strong>of</strong> methane emitted per kg <strong>of</strong><br />

stabilised waste - is assumed to be exactly the same as that <strong>of</strong> the non-stabilised<br />

material. WRATE does take into account the reduction in mass which occurs in<br />

material which is biologically pre-treated as a result <strong>of</strong> moisture loss, and this leads to<br />

a reduction in the landfill emissions – but it does not account for reduction in<br />

biodegradability, so the emissions are reduced only to a limited extent. The model,<br />

therefore, significantly underestimates the extent to which the biological component<br />

<strong>of</strong> the MBT process reduces the biological activity <strong>of</strong> material subsequently sent to<br />

landfill, biasing any assessment <strong>of</strong> residual waste facilities against this criterion. 1192<br />

Any MBT process which stabilises waste prior to landfilling is effectively penalised by<br />

the shortcomings <strong>of</strong> the model.<br />

62.1.1.3 Human Toxicity Potential<br />

The human toxicity potential is an index intending to reflect the potential harm <strong>of</strong> a<br />

unit <strong>of</strong> chemical released, based both on the inherent toxicity <strong>of</strong> the chemical and its<br />

potential dose. The default impact assessment in WRATE considers these impacts in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> kg 1,4 dichlorobenzene equivalent.<br />

Our analysis shows that landfill performs relatively well against this assessment<br />

criterion. The worst performing facility in this case is the Dundee incinerator, and<br />

thermal treatments appear less favourable in comparison to the MBT options (with<br />

the exception <strong>of</strong> the Chineham incinerator).<br />

Figure 62-3: Human Toxicity (HTP inf)<br />

80.00<br />

60.00<br />

40.00<br />

20.00<br />

0.00<br />

-20.00<br />

-40.00<br />

968<br />

29/09/09<br />

0.98<br />

3.30<br />

Landfill Ecodeco<br />

MBT<br />

12.10<br />

Generic<br />

Aero MBT<br />

Generic<br />

-5.32<br />

AD MBT<br />

14.40<br />

AD<br />

Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

Incin Elec<br />

C<br />

-27.10<br />

70.60<br />

Incin Elec<br />

D<br />

29.80<br />

Incin Elec<br />

B<br />

39.50<br />

Incin CHP<br />

C<br />

40.60<br />

Incin CHP<br />

G<br />

1192 This is a problem <strong>of</strong> the model, related to the fact that WRATE does not incorporate a landfill model<br />

per se, rather emissions are hard-coded into the model.


These results suggest a significant variation in the relative performance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

different AD and incineration options. A closer inspection <strong>of</strong> the pollution inventory<br />

reveals that results against this assessment criterion are heavily influenced by heavy<br />

metal emissions from the facility.<br />

For example, whilst the treatment and recovery stage <strong>of</strong> the Generic AD facility is<br />

indicated to result in 17.9 kg <strong>of</strong> 1,4 dichlorobenzene equivalent, the same stage<br />

within the Arrowbio AD-based MBT plant results in 43.2 kg <strong>of</strong> 1,4 dichlorobenzene<br />

equivalent. This impact is linked to a substantial differential in the emissions <strong>of</strong><br />

Chromium VI assumed to occur from the two facilities. Whilst the Generic AD process<br />

assumes an annual emission <strong>of</strong> 2.3E-06 kg Chromium VI to air (per 60,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong><br />

waste to facility) the Arrowbio AD-based MBT plant assumes 0.42 kg Chromium VI is<br />

emitted annually (from 70,000 tonnes treated at the plant).<br />

An analysis <strong>of</strong> the emissions data embedded within WRATE indicates that the former<br />

process derives its estimated Chromium VI emissions:<br />

969<br />

“from the waste gas figures and the efficiency <strong>of</strong> the purification system to<br />

reach a clean gas emissions figure”.<br />

An inspection <strong>of</strong> the same entry for the Arrowbio AD-based MBT process indicates<br />

that the data has been extrapolated from similar AD technologies in Germany as<br />

aerial emissions data is lacking. It is not clear which German technologies were<br />

referenced when compiling the model for the Arrowbio process. It does demonstrate,<br />

however, how the quest for complete inventories can bias results obtained.<br />

There is even greater variation in the performance <strong>of</strong> the different incinerator options.<br />

Here, results are heavily influenced by:<br />

� Avoided emissions <strong>of</strong> barite to water; and<br />

� Emissions <strong>of</strong> cadmium and thallium to air.<br />

The mineral barite is used as a weighting agent in the petroleum drilling industry;<br />

impacts here, therefore, relate the amount <strong>of</strong> energy generated by each option.<br />

For incineration facilities, WRATE calculates emissions to air based on emissions data<br />

supplied by plant operators. These are scaled up within the model to give an annual<br />

emission figure for the facility. Heavy metal emissions are then weighted using an<br />

estimate <strong>of</strong> the heavy metal content in the input waste (derived from waste<br />

composition supplied by the user within each bespoke scenario), divided by heavy<br />

metal content <strong>of</strong> what is termed the ‘typical waste’ composition. As an example, the<br />

cadmium emission is calculated using the following allocation formula:<br />

[Total cadmium in input waste] * [Emissions from process]<br />

[Total cadmium in ‘typical waste’]<br />

The worst performing incinerator with regard to its human toxicity potential is that<br />

located at Dundee (a fluidised bed incinerator). The Dundee incinerator is assumed to<br />

emit 0.75 kg cadmium per 120,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste; by contrast the Chineham<br />

facility emits 0.07 kg cadmium per 95,000 tonnes. Both figures relate to a series <strong>of</strong><br />

actual emissions measurements taken at each facility, and in both cases the upper<br />

measurement was used from the series.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


kg kg 1,4-dichlorobenzene 1,4-dichlorobenzene eq.<br />

eq.<br />

The allocation formula for heavy metal emissions relies on a reasonably close match<br />

between the ‘typical’ composition data used to model the facility and the measured<br />

emissions data. Use <strong>of</strong> the upper emissions estimate may result in an overestimation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the annual impacts if emissions measurement were taken at a point when material<br />

containing an exceptional amount <strong>of</strong> heavy metal was being treated.<br />

The human toxicity impacts <strong>of</strong> the treatment options are separately assessed using a<br />

different impact assessment method in Section 62.2, which shows how different the<br />

results can be. That section presents the results <strong>of</strong> this additional assessment, and<br />

highlights the limitations <strong>of</strong> the LCA approach to technology appraisal. The preceding<br />

discussion, however, highlights how sometimes obscure pollutants, and relatively<br />

casual assumptions made about them, can be highly influential in the assessment,<br />

especially against toxicity impacts where impact weightings vary enormously across a<br />

very large range <strong>of</strong> pollutants emitted / avoided. 1193<br />

62.1.1.4 Freshwater Aquatic Eco-Toxicity<br />

This index is similar to the human toxicity assessment described in Section 62.1.1.3,<br />

but is intended to measure the toxicity <strong>of</strong> a chemical to aquatic life. Impacts are also<br />

considered in terms <strong>of</strong> kg 1,4 dichlorobenzene equivalent.<br />

Figure 62-4: Freshwater Aquatic Eco-toxicity (FAETP inf)<br />

5.00<br />

0.00<br />

-5.00<br />

-10.00<br />

-15.00<br />

-20.00<br />

-25.00<br />

-30.00<br />

-35.00<br />

-40.00<br />

970<br />

29/09/09<br />

-0.29<br />

Landfill Ecodeco<br />

MBT<br />

-34.30<br />

Generic<br />

Aero MBT<br />

-24.80<br />

Generic<br />

AD MBT<br />

-26.30<br />

AD<br />

Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

-27.70<br />

Incin Elec<br />

C<br />

-15.20<br />

Incin Elec<br />

D<br />

-16.20<br />

0.23<br />

Incin Elec<br />

B<br />

Incin CHP<br />

C<br />

-8.56<br />

Incin CHP<br />

G<br />

1193 Some LCA practitioners, for this very reason, prefer to concentrate their analysis on emissions for<br />

which data is relatively robust, rather than seeking to be ‘comprehensive’ in the range <strong>of</strong> emissions<br />

analysed. The ‘comprehensive’ approach risks biasing the assessment for trivial reasons, such as the<br />

fact that inventories for some processes simply do not cover the same breadth <strong>of</strong> emissions as the<br />

inventories for others. If omitted emissions are those for which impact weightings are high, the<br />

assessment is effectively biased.<br />

-19.50


kg kg SO2 SO2 eq.<br />

eq.<br />

The results shown in Figure 62-4 indicate the MBT treatments are the most<br />

favourable options with regard to this assessment criterion whilst landfill and the<br />

Billingham incinerator perform worst.<br />

The impacts attributed through this assessment method result from two principle<br />

sources:<br />

971<br />

� Avoided vanadium emissions to water as a result <strong>of</strong> recycling ferrous metal;<br />

� Emissions <strong>of</strong> copper to water from the landfilling <strong>of</strong> combustion residues.<br />

62.1.1.5 Acidification<br />

The acidification indicator measures the potential for a pollutant to contribute to the<br />

atmospheric acidification resulting in the production <strong>of</strong> acid rain. The default impact<br />

assessment method within WRATE considers impacts in terms <strong>of</strong> kg SO2 equivalent.<br />

Table 62-1 indicates that the thermal treatments perform the worst with regard to<br />

their acidification potential. Whilst landfill fares relatively well in comparison to the<br />

incineration facilities, the best performers are the MBT facilities. Again, the Arrowbio<br />

AD-based MBT plant is the best performer against this particular assessment<br />

criterion.<br />

Table 62-1: Acidification (AP)<br />

1.50<br />

1.00<br />

0.50<br />

0.00<br />

-0.50<br />

-1.00<br />

-1.50<br />

0.10<br />

Landfill Ecodeco -0.08<br />

MBT<br />

0.14<br />

Generic<br />

Aero MBT<br />

0.06<br />

Generic<br />

AD MBT<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

AD<br />

Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

-0.92<br />

0.19<br />

Incin Elec<br />

C<br />

0.66<br />

Incin Elec<br />

D<br />

1.04<br />

Incin Elec<br />

B<br />

0.73<br />

Incin CHP<br />

C<br />

0.41<br />

Incin CHP<br />

G<br />

The Arrowbio AD-based MBT process performs favourably because the facility recycles<br />

plastic, resulting in avoided SO2 emissions (according to WRATE, this material is not<br />

recycled by the other options considered within our appraisal).<br />

The performance <strong>of</strong> incineration facilities against this criterion is heavily influenced by<br />

the amount <strong>of</strong> NOx that is assumed to be emitted.


kg kg PO4 PO4 eq.<br />

eq.<br />

62.1.1.6 Eutrophication<br />

The Eutrophication indicator measures the potential for pollutants to stimulate<br />

excessive plant growth through their release into water courses (principally nitrogen<br />

and phosphate). Impacts are considered in terms <strong>of</strong> kg PO4 equivalent within the<br />

default assessment method.<br />

The results displayed in Table 62-2 indicate that the Arrowbio AD-based MBT facility is<br />

the least favourable option in terms <strong>of</strong> the Eutrophication assessment, and that the<br />

majority <strong>of</strong> MBT facilities (with the exception <strong>of</strong> the Ecodeco plant) fare less well than<br />

the thermal treatments.<br />

Table 62-2: Eutrophication (EP1992)<br />

0.45<br />

0.40<br />

0.35<br />

0.30<br />

0.25<br />

0.20<br />

0.15<br />

0.10<br />

0.05<br />

0.00<br />

972<br />

0.41<br />

29/09/09<br />

0.09<br />

Landfill Ecodeco<br />

MBT<br />

0.27<br />

Generic<br />

Aero MBT<br />

0.24<br />

Generic<br />

AD MBT<br />

0.33<br />

AD<br />

Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

0.06<br />

Incin Elec<br />

C<br />

0.17<br />

Incin Elec<br />

D<br />

0.19<br />

Incin Elec<br />

B<br />

0.20<br />

Incin CHP<br />

C<br />

0.14<br />

Incin CHP<br />

G<br />

For the MBT treatment technologies eutrophication impacts are assumed to be<br />

caused by ammonia emissions to water resulting from the landfill element - there is a<br />

direct correlation between the amount <strong>of</strong> material sent to landfill and the<br />

performance <strong>of</strong> MBT systems against this assessment criterion. Of the MBT<br />

treatments considered here, the Arrowbio AD-based MBT facility has most material<br />

(69% <strong>of</strong> the initial mass) sent to landfill, as no part <strong>of</strong> the stabilised material is<br />

subsequently thermally treated. In contrast, the Ecodeco process sends only 16% <strong>of</strong><br />

the input waste to landfill.<br />

WRATE does not properly account for the reduction in nitrogen content that would<br />

occur as a result <strong>of</strong> the biological treatment part <strong>of</strong> the MBT process, although<br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> nitrogenous compounds are also assumed to occur during that<br />

treatment stage. There are similar problems here, therefore, as have been discussed<br />

in respect <strong>of</strong> climate change emissions.<br />

The different performance <strong>of</strong> the incineration facilities against this assessment<br />

criterion principally relates to atmospheric emissions <strong>of</strong> NOx from the plant.


62.1.2 Summary <strong>of</strong> Results<br />

In addition to the variation in performance between the different MBT options - noted<br />

in FTC analysis and confirmed by the results <strong>of</strong> appraisal presented here - our<br />

analysis indicates there is considerable variation in the performance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

incineration facilities modelled within WRATE. This is shown in Table 62-3 which<br />

shows the two most favourable options against each <strong>of</strong> the assessment criteria, along<br />

with the worst performer in each case.<br />

Table 62-3: Summary <strong>of</strong> the Best and Worst Performers<br />

Abiotic Resource<br />

Depletion<br />

Global Warming<br />

Potential<br />

973<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Performance Performance against against assess assessment assess ment crit criteria crit<br />

eria<br />

Best Best<br />

Second Second best best<br />

Worst<br />

Worst<br />

Arrowbio AD MBT Grimsby Incinerator Landfill<br />

Arrowbio AD MBT Chineham Incinerator Generic Aero MBT<br />

Human Toxicity Chineham Incinerator Generic AD MBT Dundee Incinerator<br />

Freshwater Aquatic<br />

Eco-toxicity<br />

Ecodeco MBT Arrowbio AD MBT<br />

Acidification Arrowbio AD MBT Ecodeco MBT<br />

Billingham<br />

Incinerator<br />

Billingham<br />

Incinerator<br />

Eutrophication Chineham Incinerator Ecodeco MBT Landfill<br />

Table 62-3 suggests that those facilities performing the most favourably against the<br />

six criteria are:<br />

� The Chineham incinerator;<br />

� The Arrowbio AD-based MBT and Ecodeco MBT facilities.<br />

The favourable performance <strong>of</strong> the Arrowbio AD-based MBT facility results from both<br />

the production <strong>of</strong> energy from biogas and the relatively high proportion <strong>of</strong> material<br />

recycled in comparison to the other MBT options.<br />

Whilst landfill is the least favourable option against two <strong>of</strong> the criteria, an incinerator<br />

is the worst performer in three. By contrast to the results generated within FTC’s<br />

analysis, there is little indication here that the thermal options operating in CHP mode<br />

are the most favourable – in the majority <strong>of</strong> cases the best performing incineration<br />

facility is one which generates electricity only.<br />

62.2 Limitations <strong>of</strong> the Life-cycle Assessment Approach<br />

The WRATE expert user license allows the user to carry out the life-cycle assessment<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste treatment technologies against a number <strong>of</strong> different assessment methods.


kg kg 1,4-dichlorobenzene 1,4-dichlorobenzene eq.<br />

eq.<br />

Life-cycle methodology involves the compilation <strong>of</strong> a life-cycle inventory, detailing all<br />

direct and indirect emissions (the latter relating to avoided impacts associated with<br />

energy generation and recycling). Each life-cycle assessment method assigns a series<br />

<strong>of</strong> characterisation factors (or weightings) to each <strong>of</strong> the substances in the inventory,<br />

according to their relative anticipated impact within the method. In some cases the<br />

different impact assessment methods give quite different results for the same type <strong>of</strong><br />

impact, through the use <strong>of</strong> different characterisation factors against the data<br />

contained within the same emissions inventory.<br />

An example <strong>of</strong> this is shown in Table 62-4 and Table 62-5. These figures compare the<br />

results obtained using two different impact assessment methods within WRATE to<br />

measure the terrestrial eco-toxicity <strong>of</strong> waste treatment technologies treating one<br />

tonne <strong>of</strong> residual waste. They show that whilst the CHP technologies perform<br />

relatively favourably against this criterion when assessed using the Impact 2002<br />

method, they do not fare well when the CML method is used to assess the same<br />

criterion.<br />

Further evidence <strong>of</strong> this can be seen when considering an assessment <strong>of</strong> the human<br />

toxicity associated with the different treatment technologies. Table 62-6 shows the<br />

results obtained using the Impact 2002. This method indicates the Arrowbio ADbased<br />

MBT plant as the most favourable treatment option with respect to human<br />

toxicity impacts, whilst the Billingham incinerator performs the worst against this<br />

criterion in this method. In contrast, the HTP Inf Method outlined in Section 62.1.1.3<br />

suggests that the Chineham incinerator is the most favourable treatment option,<br />

whilst the Arrowbio AD-based MBT plant performs less well in comparison to the<br />

Generic AD plant.<br />

Table 62-4: Terrestrial Eco-toxicity Assessed using the CML Method<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

-0.1<br />

-0.2<br />

-0.3<br />

974<br />

29/09/09<br />

0.0132<br />

0.174<br />

0.468<br />

Landfill Ecodeco MBT Generic Aero<br />

MBT<br />

0.358<br />

Generic AD<br />

MBT<br />

AD Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

-0.182<br />

0.0284<br />

0.502<br />

0.217<br />

0.179<br />

0.389<br />

Incin Elec C Incin Elec D Incin Elec B Incin CHP C Incin CHP G


DALY, DALY, kg kg chloroethylene<br />

chloroethylene<br />

PDF*m2*yr/kg-triethylene PDF*m2*yr/kg-triethylene glycol<br />

glycol<br />

Table 62-5: Terrestrial Eco-toxicity Assessed using the Impact 2002 Method<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

0<br />

-2<br />

-4<br />

-6<br />

975<br />

0.739<br />

Landfill Ecodeco MBT Generic Aero<br />

MBT<br />

-4.01<br />

-1.02<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Generic AD<br />

MBT<br />

-1.34<br />

AD Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

-2.78<br />

-2.35<br />

1.17<br />

4.44<br />

Incin Elec C Incin Elec D Incin Elec B Incin CHP C Incin CHP G<br />

Table 62-6: Human Toxicity Assessed using Impact 2002+ (Endpoint) Method<br />

1.20E-05<br />

1.00E-05<br />

8.00E-06<br />

6.00E-06<br />

4.00E-06<br />

2.00E-06<br />

0.00E+00<br />

-2.00E-06<br />

-4.00E-06<br />

-6.00E-06<br />

2.49E-07<br />

Landfill Ecodeco<br />

MBT<br />

-3.07E-06<br />

Generic Generic<br />

Aero MBT AD MBT<br />

-2.04E-06 -2.13E-06<br />

AD<br />

Arrowbio<br />

MBT<br />

-4.26E-06<br />

4.93E-07<br />

Incin Elec<br />

C<br />

2.60E-06<br />

Incin Elec<br />

D<br />

1.09E-05<br />

Incin Elec<br />

B<br />

8.30E-06<br />

-5.12<br />

Incin CHP<br />

C<br />

1.23E-07<br />

Incin CHP<br />

G<br />

The model used in both this analysis and FTC’s appraisal - WRATE - suffers from some<br />

significant shortcomings. The shortcomings <strong>of</strong> the model are particularly relevant<br />

-3.72


when comparing facilities which biologically treat waste prior to landfilling. This is the<br />

case especially for climate change and eutrophication.<br />

This is somewhat disappointing since climate change is one <strong>of</strong> the impact<br />

assessment categories where there is relatively good agreement as to how the impact<br />

<strong>of</strong> different emissions should be weighted. In many other impact assessment<br />

categories, particularly those related to eco-toxicity, there are some more general<br />

concerns about the weightings applied to different pollutants under different impact<br />

assessment methods.<br />

This problem is almost certainly exacerbated in WRATE because the model seeks to<br />

be comprehensive in the range <strong>of</strong> pollutants which are covered. It is almost certainly<br />

the case that the datasets which reside within the model derive from studies which<br />

vary in the degree to which they seek to record all pollutants emitted. Similar sorts <strong>of</strong><br />

bias can occur, as demonstrated above, where the model builders seek to make good<br />

for the absence <strong>of</strong> data on specific emissions with reference to other facilities.<br />

62.3 Concluding Comment<br />

The upshot <strong>of</strong> the above discussion is that:<br />

976<br />

� The model used by the STRIVE report suffers from some shortcomings which<br />

tend to bias the assessment which was carried out. This is not to say this was<br />

deliberate on the part <strong>of</strong> the authors. Rather, it makes the point that the model<br />

has some serious limitations;<br />

� The relative confidence with which the conclusions are drawn in the report is<br />

perhaps misplaced.<br />

Hence, the report’s statement that: 1194<br />

29/09/09<br />

As can be seen from an examination <strong>of</strong> the charts, a waste management<br />

scenario which includes a high energy recovery (i.e. recovery <strong>of</strong> both heat and<br />

energy) thermal treatment performs consistently well over each <strong>of</strong> the impact<br />

categories, performing best in each category. The mechanical biological<br />

treatment scenarios and the low-energy recovery scenarios have varying<br />

ranking over the impact categories.<br />

Can be traced effectively to being a function <strong>of</strong><br />

� The operation <strong>of</strong> the model, and<br />

� The choice <strong>of</strong> MBT system used in the modelling.<br />

The study’s authors later state:<br />

There is a need for further study into the emissions and environmental fate <strong>of</strong><br />

materials in MBT systems<br />

1194 Fehily Timoney & Company / Veolia Environmental Services / Ramboll (2008) Critical Analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

the Potential for Mechanical Biological Treatment for Irish <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Volume 2, Research<br />

Report, Report for the Environmental Protection Agency, September 2008.


This is clearly true, not least since there are so many potential variants. It is also true,<br />

however, that the modelling tool used does not reflect the workings <strong>of</strong> MBT systems<br />

in a particularly fair way. We understand that the Environment Agency is seeking to<br />

update the s<strong>of</strong>tware to incorporate these effects, though we have not been able to<br />

analyse these expected changes.<br />

977<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


63.0 Externalities <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options<br />

The following residual treatments are considered within our analysis:<br />

978<br />

1. Landfill <strong>of</strong> untreated material;<br />

2. Incineration (generation <strong>of</strong> electricity only);<br />

3. Two MBT treatment processes:<br />

29/09/09<br />

a. Aerobic Stabilisation (with pre-treated output sent to landfill);<br />

b. Aerobic Biodrying producing SRF sent to incineration (generating<br />

electricity only) with rejected material stabilised prior to being sent to<br />

landfill.<br />

We have considered emissions <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gases and the impacts upon air quality<br />

that are expected to result from the treatment process, including both direct and<br />

indirect impacts (the latter relating to avoided impacts associated with energy<br />

generation and the recycling <strong>of</strong> materials).<br />

Our approach is to apply external damage costs to emissions <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gases<br />

and a range <strong>of</strong> air pollutants, allowing for the quantification <strong>of</strong> impacts in monetary<br />

terms.<br />

As highlighted in Annex 61.0, this type <strong>of</strong> analysis is complex and is affected by a<br />

number <strong>of</strong> variables and parameters. The analysis that follows is focussed upon<br />

emissions to air. Whilst waste treatment processes may also in some cases affect soil<br />

and water quality, data regarding the precise nature <strong>of</strong> these impacts is less than<br />

robust. Similarly, we have not included damage costs associated with disamenity <strong>of</strong><br />

waste treatment facilities, as estimates <strong>of</strong> disamenity costs vary considerably<br />

between the different sources, and no studies are available <strong>of</strong> this nature on MBT<br />

treatment processes, whilst few are available for landfill and incineration. This<br />

omission is likely to be the more significant <strong>of</strong> the omissions if one takes the view that<br />

well-regulated processes are unlikely to have significant effects <strong>of</strong> water and soils.<br />

This section outlines the approach taken within our analysis. Section 63.1 discusses<br />

the generic assumptions which apply to each <strong>of</strong> the treatment technologies under<br />

consideration. These include assumptions relating to energy generation, and the<br />

external damage costs applied to each <strong>of</strong> the air pollutants. This is followed by<br />

sections on each <strong>of</strong> the residual waste treatment technologies in turn. A summary <strong>of</strong><br />

the results – presented in terms <strong>of</strong> the external damage costs attributed to each <strong>of</strong><br />

the treatment technologies - is provided in Section 63.6.<br />

63.1 Generic Assumptions for Treatment Technologies<br />

This section describes the underlying assumptions common to all treatment<br />

technologies under consideration within the current analysis.<br />

63.1.1 External Costs<br />

Our approach has been as follows:


979<br />

� We have used two ‘sets’ <strong>of</strong> unit damage costs, broadly corresponding to ‘low’<br />

and ‘high’ unit damage costs. We have chosen these since they appear to be<br />

the most appropriate to use for an Ireland-specific study:<br />

• the first set uses the lowest <strong>of</strong> the four Ireland-specific figures (the four<br />

figures are based on differing methodological approaches) for NH3,<br />

VOCs, SOx, NOx and PM2.5 from the Clean Air for Europe (CAFÉ)<br />

programme, and the standard figures from the Benefits Table (BeTa)<br />

database for the remaining non-GHGs. 1195 The figures are given in year<br />

2000 prices, so they are inflated to 2009 prices. Low damage costs for<br />

carbon monoxide are taken from a Danish study. 1196 For carbon<br />

dioxide, the 2009 value as outlined in an ESRI Working paper outlining<br />

a methodology for the incorporating <strong>of</strong> GHG emission costs into<br />

economic appraisal in Ireland is used, although we do have a number<br />

<strong>of</strong> concerns about the approach, and whether it genuinely represents a<br />

social cost <strong>of</strong> carbon. 1197 Damage costs for CH4 and N2O are calculated<br />

by multiplying this figure by their respective Global Warming Potentials<br />

(GWPs) <strong>of</strong> 21 and 310.<br />

• the second set uses the highest <strong>of</strong> the four Ireland-specific figures for<br />

NH3, VOCs, SOx NOx and PM2.5 from the Clean Air for Europe (CAFÉ)<br />

programme, and the standard figures from the Benefits Table (BeTa)<br />

database for the remaining non-GHGs. The figures are given in year<br />

2000 prices, so they are inflated to 2009 prices. High damage costs for<br />

carbon monoxide are taken from the same Danish study as the low<br />

costs. For carbon dioxide the high values from the Benefits Table<br />

(BeTa) database are used, and converted to 2009 prices. 1198 Damage<br />

1195 M. Holland and P. Watkiss (2002) Benefits Table Database: Estimates <strong>of</strong> the Marginal External<br />

Costs <strong>of</strong> Air Pollution in Europe, Database Prepared for European Commission DG Environment; AEAT<br />

Environment (2005) Damages per tonne Emission <strong>of</strong> PM2.5, NH3, SO2, NOx and VOCs from Each EU25<br />

Member State (excluding Cyprus) and Surrounding Seas, Report to DG Environment <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Commission, March 2005. the Clean Air for Europe programme did not derive estimates for the<br />

remaining non-GHGs.<br />

1196 COWI (2002) Valuation <strong>of</strong> External Costs <strong>of</strong> Air Pollution – Phase 1 Report (TRIP). The Danish<br />

Environmental Research Programme.<br />

1197 Tol and Lyons (2008) Incorporating GHG Emission Costs in the Economic Appraisal <strong>of</strong> Projects<br />

Supported by State Development Agencies. ESRI Working Paper No. 247. Our concerns about the<br />

applicability <strong>of</strong> this approach include whether the futures market, which has been subject to some<br />

considerable volatility, provides a reasonable indication <strong>of</strong> the social cost. While this market would<br />

represent the opportunity cost <strong>of</strong> having to import additional allowances, which could reasonably be<br />

considered a private cost, it does not necessarily follow that this equates to the social cost. Of the two<br />

variants, the model-based price at least accords with an IPPC concentration scenario, while the<br />

assumption <strong>of</strong> holding the price at the latest available futures price does not seem to us to be a<br />

credible way <strong>of</strong> representing the social cost <strong>of</strong> carbon out to 2030 (and beyond). Furthermore, there is<br />

no indication as to whether the carbon prices shown in Table 3 <strong>of</strong> the paper are in real or nominal<br />

terms.<br />

1198 There is no single published GDP deflator for Ireland covering the period from 2000 to 2009, but<br />

we have determined the correct index based on the GDP deflator for 2003 to 2007 as detailed in the<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


980<br />

29/09/09<br />

costs for CH4 and N2O are calculated by multiplying this figure by their<br />

respective Global Warming Potentials (GWPs) <strong>of</strong> 21 and 310.<br />

Table 63-1 shows the unit damage costs used.<br />

Table 63-1: Low and High Unit Damage Costs (€/tonne) in 2009 prices<br />

Emission Emission<br />

Low Low Damage Damage Cost Cost High High Damage Damage Cost<br />

Cost<br />

CO2 €26.64 €32.14<br />

CH4 €559.44 €674.86<br />

N2O €8,258.40 €9,962.16<br />

NH3 €3,213.60 €9,146.40<br />

VOCs €840.48 €2,472.00<br />

SOx €5,932.80 €17,304.00<br />

NOx €4,696.80 €13,596.00<br />

CO €1.36 €2.71<br />

Cd €25,956.00 €25,956.00<br />

Cr €21,012.00 €21,012.00<br />

Hg €7,416,000.00 €7,416,000.00<br />

Ni €2,595.60 €2,595.60<br />

Pb €741,600 €741,600<br />

Dioxin €45,732,000,000.00 €45,732,000,000.00<br />

As €98,880.00 €98,880.00<br />

PM2.5 €18,540.00 €51,912.00<br />

There remain considerable gaps in our knowledge <strong>of</strong> the environmental impacts <strong>of</strong><br />

waste management options, and even where the knowledge is ‘emergent’,<br />

straightforward approaches to valuing benefits or costs rarely exist. Some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

uncertainties involved in this kind <strong>of</strong> analysis are highlighted in the conclusions <strong>of</strong> a<br />

recent Danish study, which noted, regarding dioxins from incineration:<br />

The American Environmental Protection Agency put out a draft version <strong>of</strong> a<br />

report from a very thorough dioxin study in 2000 (US-EPA, 2000). This study<br />

Central Statistics Office’s National Income and Expenditure 2007. To this we have added information<br />

received from the <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> Finance as to the rates <strong>of</strong> price increase from 2000 to 2002, the<br />

<strong>Department</strong>’s estimate for 2008, and the <strong>Department</strong>’s forecast for 2009. The effect is to increase<br />

2000 prices by 23.6% in order to convert them to 2009 prices.


981<br />

includes a dose-response model <strong>of</strong> the relationship between dioxin and<br />

cancer mortality. This model and Danish emission and intake data are used in<br />

the present report to estimate the socioeconomic costs <strong>of</strong> dioxin emission<br />

from waste incineration in Denmark and it is estimated that these costs are<br />

about 13 DKK pr. ton <strong>of</strong> waste (the uncertainty range is 1-128 DKK/ton). This<br />

indicates that dioxin may not be one <strong>of</strong> the most important kinds <strong>of</strong> emission<br />

from a socioeconomic point <strong>of</strong> view. Even though dioxins can cause major<br />

health problems, the emissions are so limited (6,4-28,9 g pr. year) that the<br />

economic damages are probably relatively small.<br />

Considering the large number <strong>of</strong> uncertainties, the estimate <strong>of</strong> 13 DKK pr. ton<br />

has to be looked upon as an example <strong>of</strong> calculation rather than an exact price<br />

that can be used directly in economic valuation studies or cost/benefit<br />

analyses. One <strong>of</strong> the major problems <strong>of</strong> this estimate is that the doseresponse<br />

model ascribes a very high risk to dioxins. On the other hand, the<br />

estimate excludes all morbidity effects and potential damages on the<br />

environment. Consequently, it is not possible to assess whether 13 DKK pr.<br />

ton is a high or a low estimate. 1199<br />

The range <strong>of</strong> damages referred to equates to a range from £0.93 to £11.85 per tonne<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste incinerated. Considering both the scientific uncertainties in the estimation <strong>of</strong><br />

impacts, and the unresolved methodological issues which affect valuation<br />

techniques, such ranges might be considered quite unexceptional (although it should<br />

be noted that the effect <strong>of</strong> dioxins in this study is nowhere near as high as the upper<br />

end <strong>of</strong> the range quoted in the Danish study). 1200<br />

63.1.2 Omissions from the Analysis<br />

The following is a list (almost certainly not extensive) <strong>of</strong> externalities not covered / not<br />

explicitly accounted for by the study. In all cases, the omissions relate to ‘direct’ and<br />

‘avoided’ impacts:<br />

� Disamenity (including odour, nuisance)<br />

The argument that there is insufficient data available to incorporate<br />

disamenity in a cost-benefit study comparing landfill with incineration is losing<br />

1199 D. Jensen and N. Dengsoe (2004) Værdisætning af skadesomkostninger ved affaldsforbrænding -<br />

en analyse af dioxiners skadelige effekter og et egneeksempel på disse effekters<br />

samfundsøkonomiske omkostninger, TemaNord 2004:518, Copenhagen, Nordic Ministry.<br />

1200 Some take these ranges to be evidence <strong>of</strong> some shortcoming in the methodological approach, and<br />

we have heard some give this as a reason whey they prefer life-cycle assessment over cost-benefit<br />

approaches. But if LCAs appear to give a more certain view <strong>of</strong> the world, this has to be considered<br />

largely illusory. LCAs tend to reduce ‘impact assessment’ to one number, obscuring (rather than<br />

highlighting) uncertainties, and with rarely any attempt to place margins for error around the figures<br />

being generated. The scientific uncertainties have not ‘disappeared’, rather they are less explicitly<br />

acknowledged (or ignored) because <strong>of</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong> any ranges in the weightings assigned to pollutants<br />

in any given impact assessment category. This is all the more strange in LCAs since there is no attempt<br />

to pinpoint ‘impact’ (as opposed to ‘potential impact’) whereas most CBAs are at least based upon<br />

some effort to understand actual impacts upon receptors. Neither approach is perfect, but scientific<br />

uncertainties surround both.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


982<br />

29/09/09<br />

credibility. None <strong>of</strong> the impacts assessed can be said to have been estimated<br />

with a high level <strong>of</strong> certainty. The standard <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> for disamenity should not,<br />

arguably, have to be any higher. However, in comparing a wider range <strong>of</strong><br />

treatments, we have chosen to omit disamenity from the analysis. Our view is<br />

that if disamenity was to be included, incinerators located in dense urban<br />

areas would fare worst, and well-managed biological treatment facilities<br />

(including quality odour treatment) in rural areas would fare best;<br />

� Air emissions other than the following:<br />

• CO2<br />

• CH4<br />

• N2O<br />

• NH3<br />

• VOCs<br />

• PM2.5<br />

• SOx<br />

• NOx<br />

• CO<br />

• Cd<br />

• Cr<br />

• Hg<br />

• Ni<br />

• Pb<br />

• Dioxin<br />

• As<br />

� Bioaerosols<br />

It seems likely that the main risks relate to composting and anaerobic<br />

digestion where the digestion process includes a post-digestion aerobic step.<br />

However, some bioaerosols are likely to be present at all waste facilities. Key<br />

uncertainties which remain to be considered relate to the source factor as it<br />

relates to biowaste treatments (and, importantly, how the source factors might<br />

be reduced) and the exposure response relationship between the microorganisms<br />

which may be released and the population exposed.<br />

� Emissions to land<br />

No emissions to land have been. This almost certainly means that the<br />

treatment <strong>of</strong> landfills, and processes which lead to landfilling, is too<br />

favourable. Where the application <strong>of</strong> source separated organic material to land<br />

is concerned, no environmental disbenefit is assumed to occur on the basis<br />

that application rates would not lead to elevated (above prevailing levels)<br />

concentrations <strong>of</strong> potentially toxic elements. A limitation <strong>of</strong> life cycle


983<br />

assessments is that the blanket application <strong>of</strong> toxicity weightings to<br />

applications <strong>of</strong> trace concentrations <strong>of</strong> metals to soil – even where the impact<br />

on soil quality is suggested by reputable studies to be very limited – tends to<br />

suggest major impacts in terms <strong>of</strong> toxicity where none may apply;<br />

� Emissions to water<br />

The emissions to water are likely to be a greater issue for landfills and for<br />

anaerobic digestion plants (depending upon the details <strong>of</strong> the facility’s design<br />

and operation). It is sometimes assumed, in cost-benefit analyses, that the<br />

environmental costs <strong>of</strong> emissions to water are reduced, and effectively<br />

internalised, through payments for / investments in waste water treatment at<br />

waste management facilities. Our analysis includes some estimates <strong>of</strong><br />

emissions related to treatment <strong>of</strong> leachate from landfills. No other emissions<br />

are accounted for. At compost facilities, it is assumed that the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

water is re-circulated in the plant. At anaerobic digestion facilities, whether or<br />

not, and to what extent, process waters are treated at waste water treatment<br />

plants varies. Finally, pollution <strong>of</strong> water courses can be an issue for<br />

incinerators, notably where wet scrubbers are used, but in the facility modelled<br />

in this study, water pollution is not assumed to be a major issue.<br />

� Externalities associated with construction<br />

We have not considered external costs associated with construction <strong>of</strong><br />

facilities. It is generally stated that these account for a small proportion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

overall impacts. However, it is difficult to be quite so sanguine about this when<br />

a cost-benefit perspective, incorporating non-zero discount rates, is employed.<br />

All construction-related externalities occur early in time (by definition).<br />

Consequently, the construction related externalities will weigh proportionately<br />

greater in an analysis using discounting than in one where no discounting is<br />

used (for example, in most life cycle assessments). Countering this argument<br />

is the possibility that construction materials can be re-used / recycled at the<br />

end <strong>of</strong> their life.<br />

� Household time<br />

The effect on household time has not been considered in this study. The<br />

reader is referred to a recent study for a discussion <strong>of</strong> this issue; 1201<br />

� Water use at facilities<br />

This is another impact which is not captured in conventional life-cycle<br />

assessment. We have looked at the effect <strong>of</strong> compost applications on reducing<br />

the requirement for irrigation water. We have not looked at the use <strong>of</strong> water at<br />

the plants themselves. Demand is likely to be greatest at incinerators, though<br />

equally, low solids AD facilities may require considerable water. The degree to<br />

which process waters can be recirculated in the process is likely to vary (for all<br />

plant types) with detailed design.<br />

1201 See D. Hogg (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Unit-based <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Charges, Report for the OECD<br />

Environment Directorate, Working Group on <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention and recycling, May 2006.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


984<br />

� Land use<br />

Some studies have debated whether or not to assess the opportunity cost <strong>of</strong><br />

land in the assessment <strong>of</strong> externalities. 1202 Generally, however, the view tends<br />

to be adopted that land values are reflected in the cost <strong>of</strong> facilities. 1203 This<br />

has not been included in this analysis.<br />

� Transport<br />

The assumption made is that transport externalities are internalised in fuel<br />

and other transport-related duties. The degree to which this assumption holds<br />

good relates to the significance accorded to (and the approach to valuing)<br />

congestion externalities, if indeed these should be considered as external<br />

costs. It can be argued that a proportion <strong>of</strong> the costs associated with<br />

congestion are not ‘external’ ins<strong>of</strong>ar as transport decisions are made on the<br />

basis <strong>of</strong> some knowledge as to when congestion is likely to occur. Indeed, in<br />

the waste management case, service providers will be sensitive to congestionrelated<br />

issues in terms <strong>of</strong> the timing <strong>of</strong> their collection rounds. However, if<br />

marginal congestion costs are estimated on the basis <strong>of</strong> marginal additions to<br />

traffic, these can be quite high, and the assumption that existing duties<br />

internalise all externalities almost certainly breaks down. 1204 Notwithstanding<br />

these points, to the extent that the assumption might not be valid, then to the<br />

extent that one is seeking to understand changes in the transport externalities<br />

across different systems, it can reasonably be argued that these changes are<br />

unlikely to have a major influence on the analysis.<br />

63.1.3 Emissions Associated with Energy Generation<br />

All waste management processes consume, and in many cases, generate energy.<br />

Where energy is generated, it can be considered to replace a requirement for<br />

equivalent amounts <strong>of</strong> power from other sources.<br />

There are climate change and air quality impacts associated with the consumption<br />

and the generation <strong>of</strong> energy. Emissions from the use <strong>of</strong> diesel are considered within<br />

1202 For example, a Dutch study attributed significant externalities to landfill related to these costs (E.<br />

Dijkgraaf and H. R. J. Vollebergh (2004), Burn or Bury? A Social Cost Comparison <strong>of</strong> Final <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Disposal Methods, Ecological Economics, 50, 233-247).<br />

1203 This includes most, if not all, studies other than that cited in the previous footnote, including a<br />

recent Dutch study which discussed Dijkgraaf and Vollebergh’s approach (H. Bartelings, P. van<br />

Beukering, O. Kuik, V. Linderh<strong>of</strong>, F. Oosterhuis, L. Brander and A. Wagtendonk (2005) Effectiveness <strong>of</strong><br />

Landfill Taxation, R-05/05, Report Commissioned by Ministerie von VROM, November 24, 2005).<br />

1204 For example, work for the then DETR looks at the marginal costs <strong>of</strong> congestion using linear (with<br />

respect to vehicle quantities) speed-flow curves, and assuming that the value <strong>of</strong> time should be valued<br />

at something close to the average wage rate (see T. Sansom, C. Nash, P. Mackie, J. Shires and P.<br />

Watkiss (2001) Surface Transport Costs and Charges: Great Britain 1998, Report for DETR, July<br />

2001). All these (and other) assumptions are open to question to a degree. This approach tends to give<br />

high marginal costs for congestion. It gives highest costs for dense urban areas at peak hours,<br />

arguably the very time when most people are likely to internalise these costs into their decision-making<br />

processes. From this point <strong>of</strong> view, it is questionable whether the attribution <strong>of</strong> congestion costs as a<br />

‘marginal externality’ is necessarily correct, albeit it is an accepted approach in the literature.<br />

29/09/09


our analysis, as well as those associated with the use and generation <strong>of</strong> electricity.<br />

These impacts are discussed in the following sub-sections.<br />

63.1.3.1 Electricity<br />

The carbon intensity <strong>of</strong> an energy source is the quantity <strong>of</strong> GHG emissions associated<br />

with generating the energy. Where emissions are avoided as a result <strong>of</strong> generating<br />

energy from waste, assumptions regarding which source <strong>of</strong> energy is considered to<br />

have been displaced are important in determining the overall GHG benefit associated<br />

with power generation.<br />

Over the period 2005-2007, electricity demand in Ireland increased by 3.1% per<br />

annum on average. With a growing demand for electricity, the marginal source <strong>of</strong><br />

generation – that considered most likely to be newly built in the absence <strong>of</strong> capacity<br />

arising through energy from waste infrastructure – is assumed to be displaced. For<br />

Ireland the marginal source would be CCGT gas plant, representing the trend in terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> recently commissioned power generation technology in Ireland. 1205 The CO2<br />

emissions associated with generating electricity from natural gas are taken to be<br />

360g/kWh. 1206<br />

Natural gas is a very clean fuel and is thus completely combusted at CCGT plant,<br />

resulting in negligible emissions <strong>of</strong> particulates and SO2. The principal emissions to<br />

air associated with the generation <strong>of</strong> electricity using CCGT are therefore NOx and CO.<br />

The European Commission Reference Document for large combustion plant suggests<br />

a range <strong>of</strong> NOx emissions <strong>of</strong> 10-130 g/GJ electrical output depending on the size <strong>of</strong><br />

the plant and the abatement technique employed. 1207 Measures taken to reduce NOx<br />

emissions are less effective at the higher generation efficiencies. The lower end <strong>of</strong> the<br />

range reflects measurements taken at a relatively small (100 MWe) facility using SCR<br />

to reduce NOx emissions. We assume NOx emissions <strong>of</strong> 70 g/GJ electrical output for<br />

electricity generated at a new CCGT plant.<br />

CO emissions are usually lower for CCGT plant in comparison to the NOx emission,<br />

although these also vary depending on the size <strong>of</strong> the facility. We assume CO<br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> 45 g/GJ electrical output for electricity generated at a new CCGT plant<br />

based on data obtained from the aforementioned Reference Document.<br />

1205 Sustainable Energy Ireland (2008) Energy in Ireland 1990 – 2007. Available at<br />

http://www.sei.ie/Publications/Statistics_Publications/Energy_in_Ireland/Energy_in_Ireland_1990-<br />

2007.pdf (accessed May 2009)<br />

1206 BERR (2009) Fuel Mix Disclosure Data Table, UK <strong>Department</strong> for Business Enterprise & Regulatory<br />

Reform. Available at http://www.berr.gov.uk/energy/markets/electricity-markets/fuelmix/page21629.html<br />

(accessed May 2009).<br />

1207 European Commission (2006) Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control: Reference Document<br />

on Best Available Techniques for Large Combustion Plant, July 2006.<br />

985<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


63.1.3.2 Diesel<br />

We have used a figure <strong>of</strong> 3.09 kg CO2 equivalent per litre <strong>of</strong> diesel (including 0.46 kg<br />

CO2 equivalent pre-combustion emissions). External damage costs with respect to<br />

climate change associated with diesel use are therefore €0.09 per litre <strong>of</strong> diesel. 1208<br />

Data regarding the air quality impacts associated with the use <strong>of</strong> diesel within waste<br />

management facilities is taken from the BUWAL life-cycle inventory database<br />

produced by the Federal Office for the Environment in Switzerland. 1209 Total damage<br />

costs are €1.66 per litre <strong>of</strong> diesel if the high external costs are assumed, or €0.57 per<br />

litre using the lower costs. Approximately 12% <strong>of</strong> the total damage cost relates to precombustion<br />

emissions. The external costs are dominated by NOx externalities which<br />

equate to 99% <strong>of</strong> the air pollution impacts associated with diesel use.<br />

63.1.4 Emissions Avoided Through Recycling<br />

Recovery <strong>of</strong> material from the residual waste stream occurs at incineration and MBT<br />

facilities, as well as at recycling facilities.<br />

Most studies provide estimates <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gas reductions delivered by ‘front-end’<br />

collection and recovery systems, i.e. kerbside or bring recycling, followed if necessary<br />

by sorting within a Materials Recovery Facility (if collected in commingled form).<br />

Materials recovered from residual wastes, however, have higher levels <strong>of</strong><br />

contamination as a result <strong>of</strong> contact with the mixed residual waste stream.<br />

Depending upon the material, this contamination may have the following impacts:<br />

986<br />

� Rather than a ‘closed-loop’ process, materials might be recycled into lower<br />

value applications (for example, mixed glass to aggregates or plastics to<br />

“plaswood”, which deliver reduced, if any, carbon benefits); and<br />

� Prior to reprocessing, contaminated materials will require energy for cleaning<br />

processes - for example, hot-washing <strong>of</strong> plastics - and thus will deliver lower<br />

carbon benefits than clean streams.<br />

The current analysis attributes the same greenhouse gas benefits to recyclables<br />

removed from residual waste as those obtained through specific collections. For most<br />

dry recyclables, this is a broadly acceptable approach since the effects <strong>of</strong><br />

contamination are probably such as to affect price more than the associated benefits.<br />

However, the approach probably overstates the benefits associated with this practice<br />

at present, though this will be true only where it is assumed that plastics are<br />

extracted for recycling. Table 63-2 provides a summary <strong>of</strong> the values used.<br />

1208 There is relatively little difference between the high and low damage costs for climate change<br />

impacts.<br />

1209 Available from http://www.bafu.admin.ch<br />

29/09/09


Table 63-2: Emissions Avoided Through Recycling from Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Facilities<br />

Material<br />

Material<br />

987<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Avoided Avoided emissions, emissions, t t CO CO2equ CO qu / t recycled<br />

material<br />

material<br />

Dense plastic 0.7<br />

Steel 1.0<br />

Aluminium 10.5<br />

Source: WRATE / Ecoinvent database, available from http://www.environmentagency.gov.uk/research/commercial/102929.aspx<br />

The production <strong>of</strong> materials from recycled input may also result in avoided air quality<br />

impacts when the manufacture <strong>of</strong> these goods is compared to their production from<br />

virgin materials. However the air quality impacts associated with these processes are<br />

localised. Since most <strong>of</strong> the manufacturing <strong>of</strong> material (from either virgin or recycled<br />

input) occurs outside Ireland, we have not included these impacts within our analysis,<br />

as they will not have a direct impact on Irish air quality.<br />

63.1.5 Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Composition<br />

The residual waste composition used within our analysis is developed from the recent<br />

waste characterisation survey produced for the Environmental Protection Agency by<br />

RPS. 1210 This data is shown in Table 63-3.<br />

Table 63-3: Assumed Residual <strong>Waste</strong> Composition<br />

Compositional Compositional element element element<br />

%<br />

Paper<br />

Card<br />

Plastic Film<br />

Dense Plastic<br />

Newspapers 0.99%<br />

Magazines 0.66%<br />

Other recyclable paper 0.76%<br />

Non-recyclable paper 0.51%<br />

Cardboard 3.01%<br />

Card and paper packaging 8.60%<br />

Card non packaging 0.43%<br />

Liquid cartons 1.00%<br />

Unclassified paper and card 1.29%<br />

Refuse sacks and carrier bags 3.60%<br />

Packaging film 3.44%<br />

Other plastic film 0.33%<br />

PET clear 0.50%<br />

PET coloured 0.25%<br />

HDPE natural 0.36%<br />

HDPE coloured 0.18%<br />

PVC natural 0.02%<br />

1210 RPS (2009) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong> Characterisation Surveys 2008, Report for the EPA, March 2009


Textiles<br />

Misc Combustibles<br />

988<br />

29/09/09<br />

PVC coloured 0.02%<br />

Food packaging 2.58%<br />

Non-food packaging 1.29%<br />

Other 2.58%<br />

Natural man-made fibres 0.89%<br />

Unclassified 3.99%<br />

Disposable nappies 7.40%<br />

Shoes 1.05%<br />

Wood (includes furniture) 4.94%<br />

Misc Non Combustibles Unclassified 7.40%<br />

Glass<br />

Ferrous Metals<br />

Non-ferrous<br />

Putrescibles<br />

Clear bottles and jars 0.77%<br />

Green bottles and jars 0.77%<br />

Brown bottles and jars 0.47%<br />

Other glass 0.13%<br />

Food cans 1.13%<br />

Beverage cans 0.57%<br />

Batteries 0.07%<br />

Other ferrous 1.31%<br />

Aluminium foil 0.14%<br />

Aluminium beverage cans 0.29%<br />

Aluminium food cans 0.56%<br />

Garden waste 2.80%<br />

Kitchen waste 26.13%<br />

Unclassified 1.78%<br />

Fines Fines 5.07%<br />

63.2 Landfill<br />

63.2.1 Climate Change Impacts<br />

Section 63.2.1.1 discusses landfill gas generation (related to the carbon content <strong>of</strong><br />

the waste) and its capture. This is considered for the landfilling <strong>of</strong> untreated wastes<br />

and those that have been subject to pre-treatment such as occurs in an MBT facility.<br />

Assumptions regarding landfill gas management are summarised in Section 63.2.1.6<br />

which also includes a summary <strong>of</strong> the external costs associated with the climate<br />

change impacts <strong>of</strong> landfill.<br />

63.2.1.1 Landfill Gas Generation<br />

In order to capture the relationship between degradation and residence time, our<br />

model links the nature <strong>of</strong> the constituent organic compounds to the release <strong>of</strong><br />

greenhouse gases through time-dependent ‘first order decay’ functions (as is done in


the Swedish ORWARE model for controlled anaerobic processes). 1211 Emissions <strong>of</strong><br />

methane from landfill are allocated to specific years over a 150 year period. The<br />

degradation factors within the model have been validated to some extent through<br />

assessing the implied methane emissions from the materials and cross-checking<br />

against work undertaken in the United States and by the UK Environment Agency. 1212<br />

The constituent carbon fractions degrade at different speeds as a result <strong>of</strong> variations<br />

in their chemical and physical structure. Our model uses three degradation speeds to<br />

represent the varying speeds at which carbon degrades within the landfill. 1213 The<br />

simplified grouping <strong>of</strong> carbon fractions used within the model is shown in Table 63-4.<br />

Table 63-4: Simplification <strong>of</strong> Carbon Fractions for Landfill<br />

Speed Speed <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Decay Decay<br />

Carbon Carbon Fraction(s)<br />

Fraction(s)<br />

Fast Sugars<br />

Medium Fats, Proteins, Cellulose<br />

Slow Lignin and some Cellulose 1<br />

Notes<br />

1. Some cellulose is bound within the lignin and is therefore similarly resistant to<br />

degradation<br />

Source: Dalemo M (1996) The Modelling <strong>of</strong> an Anaerobic Digestion Plant and a Sewage Plant in the<br />

ORWARE Simulation Model, Rapport 213, Swedish University <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Sciences, Uppsala 1996<br />

To take account <strong>of</strong> the time pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> these emissions over the 150 year period, the<br />

damage costs for landfill emissions are discounted using a declining long-term<br />

discount rate as recommended in the UK Treasury’s Green Book. 1214 Table 63-5<br />

shows the rates at which damage costs are discounted for the relevant time periods<br />

1211 M. Dalemo (1997) The ORWARE Simulation Model - Anaerobic Digestion and Sewage Plant Submodels;<br />

Licentiate thesis, Swedish University <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Sciences, SLU, Uppsala; Dalemo M (1999)<br />

Environmental Systems Analysis <strong>of</strong> Organic <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>; The ORWARE Model and the Sewage<br />

Plant and Anaerobic Digestion Submodels, Ph D Thesis, Swedish University <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Sciences,<br />

Uppsala.<br />

1212 M. Barlaz (1997) Biodegradative Analysis <strong>of</strong> Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> in Laboratory-scale Landfills,<br />

EPA 600/R-97-071, Washington, DC: USEPA; R. Gregory and A. Revans (2000) Part One, in<br />

Environment Agency (2000) Life Cycle Inventory Development for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Operations:<br />

Landfill, Project Record P1/392/3, Bristol: Environment Agency<br />

1213 The same approach is taken in modelling other anaerobic processes, including landfill (see, for<br />

example, LQM (2003) Methane Emissions from Landfill Sites in the UK, Report for Defra, January<br />

2003). The method is not usually applied to aerobic processes, though some work <strong>of</strong> a similar nature<br />

has been undertaken for degradation <strong>of</strong> organic matter in soil (including the work by DU).<br />

1214 HM Treasury (UK) The Green Book: Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government, Treasury<br />

Guidance, http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/green_book_complete.pdf .<br />

989<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 63-5: Declining Long-Term Discount Rate as Applied to Landfill Emission<br />

Damage Costs<br />

Period Period Period <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

years years<br />

years<br />

Discount<br />

Discount<br />

rate rate<br />

rate<br />

990<br />

29/09/09<br />

0-30 30 30 31 31-75 31<br />

75 75 76 76-125 76<br />

125 125 126 126-200 126 126 200 200 201 201-300 201 201 300 300 301+ 301+<br />

301+<br />

3.5% 3.0% 2.5% 2.0% 1.5% 1.0%<br />

63.2.1.2 The Issue <strong>of</strong> Gas Capture<br />

There is some debate with regard to both the efficiency landfill gas capture and the<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> the gas that is used for energy generation. Of these, the gas capture<br />

rate is both the most sensitive and the most contested component.<br />

A previous assessment undertaken by Eunomia used a gas capture rate <strong>of</strong> 50%, an<br />

approach based upon two studies conducted on behalf <strong>of</strong> Defra by LQM and<br />

Enviros. 1215 A subsequent study conducted by ERM on behalf <strong>of</strong> Defra, however,<br />

assumed a 75% capture rate over the 100 year timeframe assessed. 1216 A<br />

subsequent ERM report acknowledged that if one moved the analysis beyond this<br />

(somewhat arbitrary) timeframe, lifetime capture rates might be around 59%. 1217<br />

Documentation supplied with the Golders model indicates that the expert review<br />

group formed as part <strong>of</strong> that study considered that 85% <strong>of</strong> the gas would be collected<br />

during the gas utilisation phases, and a lifetime 75% gas capture rate appears to<br />

have been suggested upon that basis. 1218<br />

The wider literature suggests a range <strong>of</strong> estimates for the efficiency <strong>of</strong> gas collection<br />

with a distinction being made between instantaneous collection efficiencies and the<br />

proportion <strong>of</strong> gas that can be captured over the lifetime <strong>of</strong> the landfill. 1219 Whilst<br />

1215 Eunomia (2006) A Changing Climate for Energy from <strong>Waste</strong>? Final report to Friends <strong>of</strong> the Earth,<br />

May 2006; LQM (2003) Methane Emissions from Landfill Sites in the UK, Report for Defra, January<br />

2003; Enviros, University <strong>of</strong> Birmingham, RPA Ltd., Open University and M. Thurgood (2004) <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

Environmental and Health Effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> and Similar <strong>Waste</strong>s,<br />

Final Report to Defra, March 2004.<br />

1216 ERM (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Energy from <strong>Waste</strong> and Recycling <strong>Policy</strong> on UK Greenhouse Gas Emissions,<br />

Final Report for Defra, January 2006.<br />

1217 ERM (2006) Carbon Balances and Energy Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> UK <strong>Waste</strong>s, Defra R&D<br />

project WRT 237. December 2006<br />

1218 Golder Associates (2005) Report on UK Landfill Methane Emissions: Evaluation and Appraisal <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Policies and Projections to 2050, report for Defra, November 2005<br />

1219 P. Anderson (2005) The Landfill Gas Recovery Hoax, Abstract for 2005 National Green Power<br />

Marketing Conference; USEPA (2004) Direct Emissions from Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> Landfilling, Climate<br />

Leaders Greenhouse Gas Inventory Protocol – Core Module Guidance, October 2004; K.A. Brown, A.<br />

Smith, S.J Burnley, D.J.V. Campbell, K. King and M.J.T. Milton (1999) Methane Emissions from UK<br />

Landfills, Report for the UK <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Transport and the Regions.


instantaneous collection rates for permanently capped landfilled waste can be as<br />

high as 90%, capture rates may be much lower during the operating phase <strong>of</strong> the<br />

landfill (35%) or when the waste is capped with a temporary cover (65%). 1220 In<br />

addition, gas collection is technologically impractical towards the end <strong>of</strong> the site’s life.<br />

The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) has recently stated that<br />

lifetime gas capture rates may be as low as 20%. 1221 We would consider, however,<br />

that landfills in the UK are somewhat better engineered than in the general (global)<br />

case, although a recent report by the European Environment Agency uses the IPCC<br />

figure. 1222<br />

We have assumed a landfill gas capture <strong>of</strong> 50% as our central assumption. Results<br />

obtained assuming 20% <strong>of</strong> the landfill gas is captured are also presented for<br />

sensitivity analysis.<br />

Our model assumes that waste which has been pre-treated (e.g. through an aerobic<br />

stabilisation process) will behave differently in landfill with respect to the generation<br />

<strong>of</strong> landfill gas, and that pre-treated wastes will therefore ultimately require a different<br />

form <strong>of</strong> gas management in landfill. The landfill <strong>of</strong> pre-treated waste is discussed in<br />

Section 63.2.1.5.<br />

63.2.1.3 Energy Generated from Landfill Gas<br />

Energy is generated from a variable proportion <strong>of</strong> the recovered gas. At times <strong>of</strong> high<br />

flux, emissions can be greater than the capacity <strong>of</strong> the engines and thus a proportion<br />

<strong>of</strong> the gas must be flared. At times <strong>of</strong> low flux, i.e. towards the end <strong>of</strong> the site lifetime,<br />

emissions may be too small for the gas engines to function effectively. In such a<br />

situation, the usual practice <strong>of</strong> the landfill operator is to flare the gas.<br />

LQM carried out a survey <strong>of</strong> landfill operators to estimate the total flare capacity<br />

across UK landfills. 1223 They noted within their analysis that:<br />

991<br />

There are difficulties in ascertaining the actual volumes <strong>of</strong> LFG burnt as<br />

detailed records, if they exist at all, will be held by individual site operators. It<br />

is rare to find a flow stack with a flow measurement device installed, even<br />

though the capital cost <strong>of</strong> such a device is relatively small.<br />

1220 K. Spokas, J. Bogner, J.P. Chanton, M. Morcet, C. Aran, C. Graff, Y. Moreau-Le Golvan and I. Hebe<br />

(2006) Methane Mass Balance at 3 Landfill Sites: What is the Efficiency <strong>of</strong> Capture by Gas Collection<br />

Systems? <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>, 5, pp515-525<br />

1221 IPCC (2007) Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution <strong>of</strong> Working Group III to the Fourth<br />

Assessment Report <strong>of</strong> the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz, O.R. Davidson, P.R.<br />

Bosch, R. Dave, and L.A. Meyer (eds), Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and<br />

New York, NY, USA., pp 600.<br />

1222 M. Skovgaard, N. Hedal, A. Villanueva, F. Andersen and H. Larsen (2008) Municipal <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> and Greenhouse Gases, ETC/RWM Working Paper 2008/1, January 2008.<br />

1223 Land Quality <strong>Management</strong> (2003) Methane Emissions from Landfill sites in the UK, Final Report<br />

for Defra, January 2003.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


LQM did not consider the amount <strong>of</strong> energy generated from LFG within their analysis,<br />

although they estimated the total flaring back-up capacity to be around 60% <strong>of</strong><br />

generation capacity. It is usual for landfill operators to maximise energy generation as<br />

this represents a revenue stream. We assume within the current analysis that 40% <strong>of</strong><br />

the recovered gas will be flared. Although it is acknowledged that there is some<br />

uncertainty here, the impact <strong>of</strong> this uncertainty (in terms <strong>of</strong> CO2 equivalent <strong>of</strong>fsets<br />

associated with energy generation from landfill) is relatively small.<br />

63.2.1.4 Oxidation <strong>of</strong> Landfill Gas<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the uncaptured landfill gas will be oxidised as it passes through the cap to<br />

the surface, the proportion being dependent upon the nature <strong>of</strong> the cap. The USEPA<br />

suggests a range <strong>of</strong> 10% to 25%, with clay soils at the lower end <strong>of</strong> the range and topsoils<br />

being at the higher end. This reflects a figure proposed by Brown et al in 1999 in<br />

a study on behalf <strong>of</strong> what was then the DETR. 1224 A similar value was proposed by the<br />

IPCC.<br />

However, a recently published review <strong>of</strong> the wider literature on this subject suggests<br />

that the mean fraction <strong>of</strong> methane oxidised was 36% (an average across 42 studies<br />

taken in a variety <strong>of</strong> locations). 1225 We have retained the 10% figure assumed by the<br />

IPCC and USEPA, but acknowledge that this is likely to overestimate fugitive<br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> methane occurring from landfill in many cases.<br />

63.2.1.5 Landfill <strong>of</strong> Pre-treated <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Under the very low fluxes <strong>of</strong> landfill gas assumed to occur when pre-treated wastes<br />

are landfilled, the methanotrophic bacteria within the soil cover can oxidise a much<br />

larger portion <strong>of</strong> the methane delivered them, oxidising up to 95-100% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

emission. 1225 The very low gas production resulting from landfilling MBT residues in<br />

German and Austrian cases, especially for methane, is estimated to be around 1 l<br />

CH4/m 2 *h in a typical landfill. 1226 In this case, no active landfill gas collection is<br />

possible. To prevent gas emissions into the atmosphere, a passive method <strong>of</strong><br />

oxidation <strong>of</strong> the residual emissions is necessary. A suitable approach is the use <strong>of</strong> a<br />

biologically active oxidising landfill cover, consisting <strong>of</strong> biologically active material like<br />

compost. This oxidises the methane gas during its passage through the layer.<br />

As a survey <strong>of</strong> several experimental results indicate, the oxidising capacity <strong>of</strong> soils and<br />

landfill layers are in the range <strong>of</strong> 0.01 to 16.8 l CH4/m 2*h. 1227 Most values are<br />

1224 K.A. Brown, A. Smith, S.J. Burnley, D.V.J. Campbell, K. King and M.J.T. Milton (1999) Methane<br />

Emissions from UK Landfills, A Report for the UK <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Environment, Transport and the<br />

Regions.<br />

1225 J.P. Chanton, D.K. Powelson and R.B. Green (2009) Methane Oxidation in Landfill Cover Soils, is a<br />

10% Default Value Reasonable? Journal <strong>of</strong> Environmental Quality, 38, pp 654-663.<br />

1226 Soyez, K., and Plickert, S. Mechanical-Biological Pre-Treatment <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> – State <strong>of</strong> the Art and<br />

Potentials <strong>of</strong> Biotechnology, University <strong>of</strong> Potsdam, mimeograph.<br />

1227 K. Hoering, I. Kruempelbeck, H-J. Ehrig, (1999) Long-term emission behaviour <strong>of</strong> mechanicalbiological<br />

pre-treated municipal solid waste. In: Proceedings Sardinia 99. Seventh <strong>International</strong> <strong>Waste</strong><br />

992<br />

29/09/09


etween 0.1 to 5 l CH4/m 2*h, so that a mean value <strong>of</strong> 3 l CH4/m 2*h seems realistic.<br />

Even if one considers the potential influence <strong>of</strong> temperature, water content, and the<br />

varying gas qualities, it seems entirely probable, therefore, that such a layer would be<br />

able to oxidise a very high proportion <strong>of</strong> methane from the landfill gas emanating from<br />

MBT-treated wastes. Early trials suggest that a gas oxidation layer <strong>of</strong> about 120 cm<br />

combined with a gas distribution layer <strong>of</strong> 50 cm is suitable. 1228 Fugitive emissions <strong>of</strong><br />

methane are therefore minimal in this case.<br />

The positive effects on landfill behaviour <strong>of</strong> pre-treatment can only be realised if the<br />

landfill is adapted to the conditions presented by the waste. Landfill gas capture is<br />

not necessary (the low flux makes this technically infeasible, as was previously<br />

discussed in Section 63.2.1.2) and therefore no energy is generated from the landfill<br />

gas.<br />

We have effectively modelled two landfills. In the first, we keep the characteristics <strong>of</strong><br />

the landfill the same as for general mixed waste. All that changes is that the gas<br />

generation from the treated waste is low. However, as part <strong>of</strong> a more general<br />

‘landfilling <strong>of</strong> waste’, we assume that in these situations, any gas emitted is treated<br />

as though it was coming from untreated waste.<br />

In the medium- to long-term, we would expect, particularly with the pre-treatment<br />

guidelines enforced, that landfill cells would be designed for primarily treated waste.<br />

In this case, we have modelled a second landfill kin which there is no gas capture in<br />

the conventional sense, where an active cover layer is depleted, and where, in line<br />

with the evidence cited above, 90% <strong>of</strong> the remaining methane emitted is oxidised by<br />

the landfill cover layer.<br />

63.2.1.6 Summary <strong>of</strong> Assumptions - Climate Change Impacts <strong>of</strong> Landfill<br />

Table 63-6 summarises our assumptions with regard to the management <strong>of</strong> landfill<br />

gas for untreated waste. These landfill gas capture assumptions result in total climate<br />

change impacts <strong>of</strong> €79.80 per tonne <strong>of</strong> untreated waste to landfill if the high external<br />

costs are assumed, or €63.06 if the lower damage costs are applied. The totals<br />

include emissions associated with energy used at the landfill (although these are<br />

insignificant in comparison to the direct emissions from the process).<br />

<strong>Management</strong> and Landfill Symposium. S Margherita di Pula, Caligari, Italy, 4-8 October 1999. pp 409-<br />

418.<br />

1228 Humer, M.; Lechner, P.: Design <strong>of</strong> a landfill cover layer to enhance methane oxidation - results <strong>of</strong> a<br />

two year field investigation. In: Christensen, T.H.; Cossu, R.; Stegmann, R. (Eds): Proc. Sardinia 2001,<br />

8. Int. <strong>Waste</strong> management and Landfill symposium, Vol. 2, 541-550, Cagliari, 2001.<br />

993<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 63-6: Landfill Gas <strong>Management</strong> – Untreated <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Parameter Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

Proportion <strong>of</strong> methane captured (central assumption) 1 50%<br />

Proportion <strong>of</strong> captured methane used for energy generation 60%<br />

Proportion <strong>of</strong> captured methane that is flared 40%<br />

Efficiency <strong>of</strong> electricity generation, landfill gas engine 35%<br />

Rate <strong>of</strong> oxidation <strong>of</strong> methane within the landfill cover 10%<br />

Notes<br />

994<br />

1. Results obtained assuming 20% <strong>of</strong> the gas is captured are considered as sensitivity<br />

analysis<br />

Table 63-7 outlines the central assumptions used to model the behaviour <strong>of</strong> pretreated<br />

waste in landfill.<br />

Table 63-7: Landfill Gas <strong>Management</strong> – Pre-treated <strong>Waste</strong> (Central Assumptions)<br />

Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

Proportion <strong>of</strong> methane captured 0%<br />

Rate <strong>of</strong> oxidation <strong>of</strong> methane within the landfill cover 90%<br />

Notes<br />

We also present results assuming the same landfill gas management as described in Table<br />

63-6 for sensitivity analysis<br />

63.2.2 Air Quality Impacts <strong>of</strong> Landfill<br />

63.2.2.1 Landfill <strong>of</strong> Untreated <strong>Waste</strong>s<br />

Whilst landfill gas is principally comprised <strong>of</strong> methane and carbon dioxide,<br />

approximately 1% <strong>of</strong> the volume <strong>of</strong> the gas is made up <strong>of</strong> trace elements. This can<br />

29/09/09


include up to 150 substances including halogenated organics, organo-sulphur<br />

compounds and aromatic hydrocarbons depending on the nature <strong>of</strong> the waste. 1229<br />

The gases which are emitted in any one year are assumed to be related to the<br />

quantity <strong>of</strong> methane or CO2 produced, depending upon whether one is considering<br />

raw gas or gas once combusted (Table 63-8). Methane emissions to the atmosphere<br />

and methane emissions captured are both used to estimate, on a proportional basis,<br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> different trace gases in a given year using the relative composition <strong>of</strong><br />

gas outlined in below. The way this is done is to normalise the concentrations (by<br />

weight) so that:<br />

995<br />

� Where gas is flared, the emissions <strong>of</strong> other gases are calculated with<br />

reference to the studies by Enviros et al and White et al. The way this is done<br />

is by calculating the CO2 content <strong>of</strong> flared gas and calculating the emissions <strong>of</strong><br />

other gases through the quantities relative to CO2 as specified in the two<br />

studies mentioned;<br />

� A similar approach is used to calculate fugitive emissions, but in this case, the<br />

other emissions are calculated relative to the calculated quantity <strong>of</strong> methane<br />

emissions; and<br />

� For gas which is emitted from the gas engine, the emissions <strong>of</strong> other gases are<br />

calculated using the quantities estimated in other studies relative to<br />

calculated CO2 emissions.<br />

There are some inconsistencies in this approach, the principal one being that the<br />

White et al data make little allowance for changes in the level <strong>of</strong> oxidation <strong>of</strong> methane<br />

through the cap <strong>of</strong> the landfill site. Our model incorporates this as a variable. It is<br />

important to appreciate here that oxidation may appear not only at the cap (and<br />

typical estimates in the literature are 10%), but also in the leachate, so that total<br />

oxidation <strong>of</strong> methane to carbon dioxide may be greater than is sometimes suggested.<br />

Landfills produce less <strong>of</strong> the pollutants for which dose response functions are<br />

tolerably well known. No external damage costs have therefore been developed for<br />

many <strong>of</strong> pollutants listed in Table 63-8. Externalities associated with the non<br />

greenhouse gas air pollutants result in damage costs totalling €4.92 per tonne <strong>of</strong><br />

landfilled waste under the high externalities, or €2.07 if the lower values are<br />

assumed. These figures include impacts associated with the use <strong>of</strong> diesel at the<br />

facility, and a small amount <strong>of</strong> avoided emissions resulting from the generation <strong>of</strong><br />

electricity from landfill gas.<br />

1229 Komex (2002) Investigation <strong>of</strong> the Composition and Emissions <strong>of</strong> Trace Components in Landfill<br />

Gas, R&D Technical Report P1-438/TR for the Environment Agency, Bristol.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 63-8: Non Greenhouse Gas Emissions to Air from Landfilling<br />

996<br />

29/09/09<br />

Emissions Emissions mg/Nm mg/Nm3<br />

landfill landfill gas<br />

gas<br />

Fugitiv Fugitive Fugitiv<br />

Ratio Ratio to<br />

to<br />

CH CH4 CH<br />

Flaring Flaring<br />

Flaring<br />

Ratio Ratio to<br />

to<br />

CO CO2 CO<br />

Generation<br />

Generation<br />

Ratio Ratio to to<br />

to<br />

CO CO2 CO<br />

Source<br />

Source<br />

Methane 1 0.001818 0.005714 Enviros<br />

Carbon dioxide 1.733333 1 1 Enviros<br />

Carbon monoxide 3.03E-05 4.09E-04 4.09E-04 White et al<br />

Hydrogen sulphide 4.66E-04 1.69E-08 1.69E-08 White et al<br />

Hydrogen chloride 2.67E-06 8.64E-05 1.14E-05 Enviros<br />

Hydrogen fluoride 5.33E-07 1.82E-05 1.14E-05 Enviros<br />

Chlorinated HC 8.10E-05 5.10E-06 5.10E-06 Enviros<br />

Dioxins and furans 0 3.36E-13 5.43E-13 Enviros<br />

Total Particulates 0 3.64E-05 0.00002 Enviros<br />

Nitrogen oxides 0 0.000455 0.002571 Enviros<br />

Sulphur dioxide 0 0.000545 0.0002 Enviros<br />

Cadmium 0 0 2.86E-07 Enviros<br />

Chromium 7.12E-08 1.25E-08 1.25E-08 White et al<br />

Lead 2.00E-08 2.49E-09 2.49E-09 White et al<br />

Mercury 1.41E-08 2.49E-09 4.57E-09 Enviros<br />

Zinc 1.68E-07 6.64E-11 6.64E-11 White et al<br />

Nickel 0 0 3.71E-08 Enviros<br />

Arsenic 0 0 4.57E-09 Enviros<br />

Total VOCs 0.000333 7.73E-06 0 Enviros<br />

Non-methane VOCs 0 8.64E-06 8.57E-05 Enviros<br />

1,1-dichloroethane 0.000036 0 0 Enviros<br />

Chloroethane 1.33E-05 0 0 Enviros<br />

Chloroethene 1.47E-05 0 0 Enviros<br />

Chlorobenzene 0.000032 0 0 Enviros<br />

Tetrachloroethene 0.000044 3.64E-08 5.71E-07 Enviros<br />

Poly-chlorinated biphenyls 0 0 0 White et al<br />

Benzene 3.2E-06 0 0 Enviros<br />

Source: Adapted from White P R, Franke M and Hindle P (1995) Integrated Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>:<br />

A Lifecycle Inventory, Blackie Academic & Pr<strong>of</strong>essional, Chapman and Hall; Enviros, University <strong>of</strong><br />

Birmingham, RPA Ltd., Open University and Thurgood M (2004) <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Environmental and Health<br />

Effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> and Similar <strong>Waste</strong>s, Final Report to Defra,<br />

March 2004


63.2.2.2 Landfill <strong>of</strong> Pre-treated <strong>Waste</strong>s<br />

Whilst data relating to measurement <strong>of</strong> trace components in fugitive emissions <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill gas from untreated waste is relatively limited, even less research has been<br />

undertaken into those from pre-treated wastes. 1230<br />

Most MBT processes use bi<strong>of</strong>ilters (or in limited cases regenerative thermal oxidation<br />

(RTO) techniques) to capture trace components from the exhaust gas produced<br />

during the stabilisation phase. It would seem logical that there will be fewer trace<br />

components emitted through fugitive emissions <strong>of</strong> gas once the output is resident in<br />

landfill following the pre-treatment process.<br />

Optimized bi<strong>of</strong>ilters can remove 50-70% <strong>of</strong> the total organic content <strong>of</strong> the waste gas<br />

generated during these processes, although their efficiency is in part determined by<br />

the volume <strong>of</strong> gas produced. 1231 Typical values for efficiency <strong>of</strong> compound removal<br />

are shown in Table 63-9.<br />

Table 63-9: Bi<strong>of</strong>ilter Efficiencies <strong>of</strong> MBT Treatment Process<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> Gas Gas Gas Component Component / / Substance Substance Group Group<br />

Bi<strong>of</strong>ilter Bi<strong>of</strong>ilter Efficiency Efficiency %<br />

%<br />

Aldehydes 75%<br />

Alkanes 75%<br />

Alcohols 90%<br />

AOX 40%<br />

Aromatic hydrocarbons (benzene) 40%<br />

Aromatic hydrocarbons (toluene, xylene) 80%<br />

NMVOC 83%<br />

PAK, PCB, PCDD/F 40%<br />

Odour 95% - 99%<br />

Ammonia 90%<br />

Source: Binner E (2002) The Impact <strong>of</strong> Mechanical-Biological Pre-treatment on the Landfill Behaviour<br />

<strong>of</strong> Solid <strong>Waste</strong>s, Biological treatment <strong>of</strong> Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong>: Technical aspects, Workshop 8-10 April<br />

2002, Brussels, pp355-372<br />

A reduction in the externalities associated with emissions <strong>of</strong> the trace elements found<br />

in landfill gas can be expected for pre-treated wastes. Given the lack <strong>of</strong> data available<br />

for such material, however, we have applied the values in Table 63-8 for both types <strong>of</strong><br />

wastes. In this context, we acknowledge that our results will underestimate the overall<br />

reduction in externalities that will occur as a result <strong>of</strong> treatment <strong>of</strong> wastes at MBT<br />

facilities.<br />

1230 It should be noted that levels <strong>of</strong> trace components in landfill gas from untreated wastes are much<br />

lower than in typical emissions from incinerators.<br />

1231 K. Fricke and W. Bidlingmaier (2002) Gaseous and Sewage Emissions in Mechanical-Biological<br />

Rest <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment, Biological Treatment <strong>of</strong> Biodegradable <strong>Waste</strong>: Technical Aspects, Workshop 8-<br />

10 April 2002, Brussels, pp341-354.<br />

997<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


63.3 Incineration<br />

63.3.1 Climate Change Impacts <strong>of</strong> Incineration<br />

Greenhouse gas emissions occurring as a result <strong>of</strong> the incineration <strong>of</strong> waste will be<br />

dependent upon the carbon content <strong>of</strong> the dry material, along with the overall<br />

efficiency <strong>of</strong> energy generation that results from the combustion <strong>of</strong> that material.<br />

Table 63-10 details the carbon content <strong>of</strong> waste components together with their<br />

energy and moisture content.<br />

Table 63-10: Carbon Contents and Energy Content for Materials in the <strong>Waste</strong> Stream<br />

998<br />

29/09/09<br />

Total Total C C (% fm)<br />

Proportion Proportion <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> C<br />

C<br />

that that is is non non<br />

non<br />

fossil fossil2<br />

Energy<br />

Energy<br />

content content (lower<br />

(lower<br />

heating heating value<br />

value<br />

as as received)<br />

received)<br />

MJ MJ per per per kg kg3<br />

Typical<br />

Typical<br />

moisture<br />

moisture<br />

content<br />

content<br />

Paper 32% 100% 11.5 18%<br />

Card 30% 100% 11.5 24%<br />

Dense plastic 1 76% 20.0 – 32.0 18%<br />

Plastic film 74% 23.0 22%<br />

Textiles 29% 50% 15.0 19%<br />

Glass 0% 0 2%<br />

Ferrous metal 0% 0 3%<br />

Non ferrous metal 0% 0 5%<br />

Wood 23% 100% 14.5 41%<br />

Garden waste 26% 100% 5.0 45%<br />

Food waste 13% - 20% 100% 4.0 – 5.0 58% - 71%<br />

Misc. combustibles 40% 50% 14.5 41%<br />

Misc. non combustibles 7% 2.7 6%<br />

Fines 17% 100% 4.5 41%<br />

Notes<br />

1. The lower values represent PVC material; the upper end <strong>of</strong> the range HDPE bottles<br />

2. This results in an overall biogenic carbon content <strong>of</strong> 54% (using the composition analysis<br />

provided in Table 63-3)<br />

3. The overall energy content <strong>of</strong> residual waste (as received at facility) is 10.8 MJ per kg, based on<br />

the composition analysis provided in Table 63-3<br />

Sources: Vito (2001) Procesbeschrijving Afvalverwerkingstechnieken: Integrale Miliestudies; Dalemo M<br />

(2004) The Modelling <strong>of</strong> an Anaerobic Digestion Plant and a Sewage Plant in the Orware Simulation<br />

Model: Swedish University <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Sciences, Report 213; Beker D and Cornelissen A (2006)<br />

Chemische Analyse Van Huishoudelijk Restafval Resultaten 1994 En 1995, Dutch National Institute <strong>of</strong><br />

Public Health and the Environment, November 2006; The National Household <strong>Waste</strong> Analysis<br />

Programme (1992); Energy Research Centre <strong>of</strong> the Netherlands (u.d.) Phyllis Database: The<br />

Composition <strong>of</strong> Biomass and <strong>Waste</strong>


63.3.1.1 Energy Use at Incineration Facilities<br />

The energy usage <strong>of</strong> the plant depends upon the scale <strong>of</strong> plant, and the nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

flue gas cleaning system. It also depends upon the presence or otherwise <strong>of</strong>:<br />

999<br />

� Mechanical pre-treatment systems;<br />

� Incineration air preheating;<br />

� Equipment for re-heating <strong>of</strong> flue gas;<br />

� <strong>Waste</strong> water evaporation plant;<br />

� Flue gas treatment systems with high pressure drops (which demand more<br />

powerful fans); and<br />

� Changes in the energy content <strong>of</strong> input waste (necessitating use <strong>of</strong> fuel to<br />

maintain minimum combustion temperatures).<br />

ERM’s analysis suggests 3.9 kWh electricity is consumed per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste treated<br />

at an incinerator, with process diesel use indicated as 1.2 kg <strong>of</strong> per tonne <strong>of</strong><br />

waste. 1232 They arrived at these figures using Environment Agency data collected for<br />

the development <strong>of</strong> the waste model WRATE. However, they note in their report that:<br />

These process data were used as a substitute for all thermal treatment<br />

processes. In reality the ancillary requirements <strong>of</strong> each will differ, but within<br />

the context <strong>of</strong> the research the more important parameter relates to the<br />

energy conversion efficiency <strong>of</strong> the process.<br />

ERM’s energy consumption figures appear to be very low in comparison to values<br />

given in the wider literature. The Draft BREF note for Incineration gives figures <strong>of</strong>: 1233<br />

� Electricity use<br />

62 kWh per tonne – 257 kWh per tonne, average 142 kWh per tonne;<br />

� Heat demand<br />

72 GJ thermal energy per tonne – 3,366 GJ thermal energy per tonne, average<br />

433 GJ thermal energy per tonne.<br />

These, in turn, are far higher than figures suggested in, for example, reports by<br />

Erichsen and Hauschild (46 kWh electricity per tonne) though this figure reflects only<br />

the operation <strong>of</strong> gas cleaning equipment. 1234 The Flemish Institute for Technological<br />

1232 ERM (2006) Carbon Balances and Energy Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> UK <strong>Waste</strong>s, Defra R&D<br />

Project WRT 237)<br />

1233 A BREF note is a note prepared by the Joint Research Centre <strong>of</strong> the European Commission to give<br />

guidance to Member States as to what is implied by ‘Best Available Techniques’ under the Directive on<br />

Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control. European Commission (2005) Integrated Pollution<br />

Prevention and Control, Draft Reference Document on the Best Available Techniques for <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Incineration, Final Draft, May 2005.<br />

1234 L. Hanne, L. Erichsen and M. Hauschild (2000) Technical Data for <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration -<br />

Background for Modeling <strong>of</strong> Product Specific Emissions in a Life-cycle Assessment Context, Elaborated<br />

as part <strong>of</strong> the EUREKA project EUROENVIRON 1296: LCAGAPS, sponsored by the Danish Agency for<br />

Industry and Trade, April 2000.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Research (VITO) gave the following consumption <strong>of</strong> energy for processes with and<br />

without SCR: 1235<br />

1000<br />

� Natural gas: 7.2 m 3 per tonne<br />

� Oil: 4 kg per tonne (or 4.7 litres per tonne)<br />

� Electricity use (per tonne): 80 kWh with Selective Non-Catalytic Reduction<br />

(SNCR) pollution abatement, 85 kWh with Selective Catalytic Reduction (SCR)<br />

abatement.<br />

To ensure the catalyst is not contaminated by other elements within the flue gas the<br />

SCR abatement system is typically located just prior to the emissions stack, which<br />

requires the 200°F flue gas to be reheated using additional electrical energy. 1236 Use<br />

<strong>of</strong> SNCR and SCR systems is discussed further in Section 63.3.2 with respect to the<br />

air quality impacts <strong>of</strong> these facilities.<br />

CEWEP’s survey <strong>of</strong> 97 facilities during 2001-2004 suggested the average electricity<br />

used by incineration processes was 78 kWh per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste input. 1237 We use the<br />

CEWEP figure for electricity consumption with SNCR and VITO’s figures for energy use<br />

assuming SCR within the current analysis. We have also used VITO’s data for the<br />

natural gas and diesel usage.<br />

63.3.1.2 Efficiencies <strong>of</strong> Electricity Generation<br />

The efficiency <strong>of</strong> generation <strong>of</strong> electricity by an incinerator may be quoted gross, or<br />

net <strong>of</strong> any energy used in the plant itself. The energy use in the plant depends partly<br />

upon the nature <strong>of</strong> the flue gas cleaning system used, but also upon a range <strong>of</strong> other<br />

factors. The relationship to flue gas cleaning is important since it seems likely that as<br />

standards for abatement have improved, so the energy used in achieving those levels<br />

<strong>of</strong> abatement has increased also.<br />

ERM suggested gross efficiencies <strong>of</strong> 20-27% for conventional incineration with steam<br />

cycle electricity generation in a recent report for Defra. 1238 Fichtner quotes a ‘realistic<br />

range’ for net electrical efficiency <strong>of</strong> 19-27%. 1239 The highest figures we have seen<br />

quoted are those quoted in the context <strong>of</strong> the Belvedere Inquiry where it was claimed<br />

that a net efficiency <strong>of</strong> 27% would be achieved. This was based around assumptions<br />

1235 VITO (2000) Vergelijking van Verwerkingsscenario’s voor Restfractie van HHA en Niet-specifiek<br />

Categorie II Bedrijfsafval, Final Report<br />

1236 Note that this is not always the case – see European Commission (2005) Integrated Pollution<br />

Prevention and Control, Draft Reference Document on the Best Available Techniques for <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Incineration, Final Draft, May 2005.<br />

1237 I. Riemann (2006) CEWEP Energy Report (Status 2001-2004): Results <strong>of</strong> Specific Data for Energy,<br />

Efficiency Rates and Coefficients, Plant Efficiency Factors and NCV <strong>of</strong> 97 European W-t-E Plants and<br />

Determination <strong>of</strong> the Main Energy Results, updated July 2006.<br />

1238 ERM (2006) Carbon Balances and Energy Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> UK <strong>Waste</strong>s, Defra R&D<br />

Project WRT 237).<br />

1239 Fichtner Consulting Engineers Limited (2004) The Viability Of Advanced Thermal Treatment Of<br />

MSW In The UK, ESTET, March 2004.<br />

29/09/09


<strong>of</strong> a thermal efficiency <strong>of</strong> 84% and an electrical efficiency <strong>of</strong> 35%. These are<br />

optimistic in the context <strong>of</strong> efficiencies currently achieved and are likely to be<br />

deliverable only at large operating scales. The Draft BREF note gave no case where<br />

the net export <strong>of</strong> electricity exceeded 18%. 1240 A survey <strong>of</strong> 25 incinerators across<br />

Europe generating electricity only reported a maximum gross energy efficiency <strong>of</strong><br />

27.9% with a weighted mean efficiency <strong>of</strong> 21.8% across the 25 facilities (the mean<br />

net efficiency was given as 17.7%). 1241 The current analysis uses a gross efficiency <strong>of</strong><br />

27%, reflecting the top end <strong>of</strong> the range quoted by ERM and the CEWEP survey.<br />

N2O emissions are modelled based on previous research undertaken by Eunomia on<br />

behalf <strong>of</strong> WRAP. 1242 The considerable uncertainty with respect to these emissions is<br />

acknowledged within the EU BREF note, which provided a range <strong>of</strong> 5.5 – 66 g N2O per<br />

tonne <strong>of</strong> waste treated by the facility. We use the mid point <strong>of</strong> these values within the<br />

current analysis. CH4 emissions are negligible from incineration facilities.<br />

The efficiency with which metals are recovered from incineration facilities is modelled<br />

based on a survey <strong>of</strong> Dutch facilities. 1243<br />

Table 63-11 summarises the assumptions for incineration discussed previously.<br />

Table 63-11: Assumptions for Incineration<br />

Parameter Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

Gross electrical generation efficiency 27%<br />

Electricity demand for flue gas cleaning 78 kWh / t input<br />

Diesel use by process 4.7 l / t input<br />

Use <strong>of</strong> natural gas by process 7.2 m 3 / t input<br />

Recycling <strong>of</strong> bottom ash 50%<br />

CH4 emissions from process 0 kg CH4 / t<br />

N2O emissions from process 0.04 kg N2O / t<br />

Recovery rate for ferrous metals 70%<br />

Recovery rate for non-ferrous metals 30%<br />

1240 European Commission (2005) Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control, Draft Reference<br />

Document on the Best Available Techniques for <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration, Final Draft, May 2005.<br />

1241 I. Riemann (2006) CEWEP Energy Report (Status 2001-2004): Results <strong>of</strong> Specific Data for Energy,<br />

Efficiency Rates and Coefficients, Plant Efficiency Factors and NCV <strong>of</strong> 97 European W-t-E Plants and<br />

Determination <strong>of</strong> the Main Energy Results, updated July 2006.<br />

1242 Eunomia (2007) Emissions <strong>of</strong> Nitrous Oxide from <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment Processes, Report to WRAP,<br />

July 2007.<br />

1243 L. Muchova and P. Rem (2008) Wet or Dry Separation: <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> Bottom Ash in Europe,<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> World Magazine, 9(3).<br />

1001<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


63.3.2 Air Quality Impacts <strong>of</strong> Incineration<br />

Typical air pollution control (APC) technology installed in incinerators located in the UK<br />

comprises <strong>of</strong>:<br />

1002<br />

� Bag filters, used to trap polluted dust (particulate matter) entrained with the<br />

exhaust gases;<br />

� Semi dry flue gas scrubbing involving the use <strong>of</strong> lime neutralizes acidic<br />

pollutants (such as SOx) within the flue gas;<br />

� Selective Non-Catalytic Reduction (SNCR) processes, used to thermally reduce<br />

NOx by injection <strong>of</strong> a reducing agent (ammonia or urea) into the post<br />

combustion flue gas;<br />

� Activated carbon to deal with dioxin (and furan) formation.<br />

Whilst SNCR processes typically allows the incinerator to meet WID with respect to<br />

NOx emissions, use <strong>of</strong> Selective Catalytic Reduction (SCR) techniques results in<br />

significant further reduction in NOx. SCR involves the addition <strong>of</strong> ammonia and the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> a catalyst (usually made <strong>of</strong> titanium oxide) to convert the NOx and ammonia<br />

into steam and nitrogen. 1244 The reduction in NOx is typically achieved at the expense<br />

<strong>of</strong> additional energy expenditure, as has been previously discussed in Section<br />

63.3.1.1. 1245<br />

NOx emissions have a significant influence on the damage costs attributed to the air<br />

pollution from waste incineration facilities. Reductions in NOx emissions results in a<br />

considerable improvement in the performance <strong>of</strong> the facility with respect to external<br />

costs attributed to the non greenhouse gas air pollution impacts.<br />

A significant proportion <strong>of</strong> the NOx emission from waste incineration is generated by<br />

the thermal process itself, and is not therefore directly linked to the nitrogen content<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste entering the facility. Data on the chemical constituents <strong>of</strong> waste varies<br />

considerably between different literature sources with the nitrogen content being<br />

particularly variable, largely reflecting the natural variation in the nitrogen content <strong>of</strong><br />

organic material (likely to be the main source <strong>of</strong> nitrogen within residual waste). We<br />

have therefore based our assessment <strong>of</strong> the air pollution impacts <strong>of</strong> incinerators<br />

upon emissions data, rather than linking to specific chemical elements within the<br />

composition.<br />

Our analysis considers emissions from two types <strong>of</strong> incinerator:<br />

1. A facility that meets the <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration Directive (WID), typical <strong>of</strong> those<br />

that have installed SNCR to reduce NOx emissions;<br />

2. A facility that significantly out-performs the requirements <strong>of</strong> the WID through<br />

the installation <strong>of</strong> SCR and wet scrubbing techniques. Emissions are based on<br />

1244 The ammonia is added to support the reduction reaction.<br />

1245 To ensure the catalyst is not contaminated by other elements within the flue gas the SCR system is<br />

typically located just prior to the emissions stack. This requires the flue gas to be reheated using<br />

additional electrical energy.<br />

29/09/09


1003<br />

data obtained from plant operating in the Netherlands with this type <strong>of</strong><br />

equipment installed.<br />

Emissions data for the facilities are detailed in Table 63-12.<br />

Table 63-12: Emissions from Incineration Facilities<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

WID WID compliant compliant facility facility Significantly Significantly out out-performs out performs WID WID2<br />

mg/Nm mg/Nm3<br />

g g / / t t waste waste1<br />

mg/Nm mg/Nm3<br />

g g g / / t t waste<br />

waste<br />

PM10 / dust 3 10.0 61.0 0.5 3.0<br />

Dioxin (ng ITEQ/Nm 3 ) 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

NOx 200.0 1,220.0 45.0 274.5<br />

SO2 50.0 305.0 1.0 4.8<br />

HF 10.0 6.1 0.0 0.0<br />

HCl 1.0 61.0 0.5 1.2<br />

CO 50.0 305.0 10.0 55.2<br />

NMVOC 10.0 61.0 0.5 3.0<br />

Total heavy metal 0.5 3.0 0.0 0.2<br />

Notes:<br />

1. Assumes an exhaust gas exit volume <strong>of</strong> 140 Nm 3/s, based on data provided by a<br />

650,000 tonne per annum incinerator located in Paris (Source: ExternE)<br />

2. Assumes the use <strong>of</strong> SCR and wet scrubbing techniques to reduce emissions<br />

3. 70% <strong>of</strong> PM10 is assumed to be PM2.5 (Source: Chang et al)<br />

Sources: Information Centre for Environmental Licensing (2002) Dutch Notes on BAT for the<br />

Incineration <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong>, Report for the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Housing, Spatial Planning and the Environment, The<br />

Netherlands, February 2002; European Commission (2006) Integrated Pollution Prevention and<br />

Control: Reference Document on Best Available Techniques for the <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment Industries,<br />

August 2006; ExternE (1999) Externalities <strong>of</strong> Energy, Vol 10: National Implementation, prepared by<br />

CIEMAT for the European Commission, Belgium; Chang M B, Huang C K, Wu J J, and Chang S H (2000)<br />

Characteristics <strong>of</strong> heavy metals on particles with different sizes from municipal solid waste<br />

incineration, Journal <strong>of</strong> Hazardous Materials 79(3): pp229-239<br />

Air pollution control residues from waste incineration facilities consist <strong>of</strong> a mix <strong>of</strong><br />

unspent reagents and chemicals extracted from the flue gas. They are typically<br />

treated as hazardous waste and are usually required to be sent to hazardous waste<br />

landfills. Chlorine, sulphur, and heavy metals are likely to be concentrated in the air<br />

pollution control residues produced by incinerators. Ironically, the better flue gas<br />

cleaning systems perform, the more likely it becomes that toxic materials are<br />

concentrated in these residues.<br />

Several recent studies indicate that long-term impacts <strong>of</strong> landfilling this hazardous<br />

material may be significant. In a Dutch study comparing the costs and benefits <strong>of</strong><br />

landfill with those <strong>of</strong> incineration, the environmental damages associated with air


pollution control residues were considered as the most important externality<br />

associated with treatment in an incineration facility. 1246<br />

Another recent life-cycle study suggests:<br />

1004<br />

29/09/09<br />

‘The evaluation <strong>of</strong> waste incineration technologies largely depends on the<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> heavy metal emissions from landfills and the weighting <strong>of</strong> the<br />

corresponding impacts at different points in time. Unfortunately, common LCA<br />

methods hardly consider spatial and temporal aspects.’ 1247<br />

Using a geochemical model to model some pollutants, the same study concluded:<br />

‘Landfills might release heavy metals over very long time periods ranging from<br />

a few thousand years in the case <strong>of</strong> Cd to more than 100,000 years in the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> Cu. The dissolved concentrations in the leachate exceed the quality<br />

goals set by the Swiss water protection law (GSchV) by a factor <strong>of</strong> at least 50.’<br />

These impacts are only likely to be significant in the much longer term, and as such<br />

have been excluded from the current analysis.<br />

63.3.2.1 Summary <strong>of</strong> Air Quality Impacts <strong>of</strong> Incineration Facilities<br />

The principal determinant <strong>of</strong> air quality damage costs associated with incineration<br />

facilities relates to the NOx externalities – both with respect to direct emissions from<br />

the treatment process and emissions generated through the use <strong>of</strong> diesel in the<br />

facility. A proportion <strong>of</strong> the impact is <strong>of</strong>fset by NOx emissions avoided through the<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> electrical energy (as discussed in Section 63.1.3.1).<br />

Table 63-13 details the damages resulting from non greenhouse gas air pollutants<br />

emitted at incineration facilities. These externalities are calculated using the<br />

emissions data provided in Table 63-12 and the damage costs for the pollutants<br />

provided in (cross reference). 1248<br />

1246 E. Dijkgraaf and H. Vollebergh (2004) Burn or Bury? A Social Cost Comparison <strong>of</strong> Final <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Disposal Methods, Ecological Economics, 50: pp233-247.<br />

1247 S. Hellweg (2000) Time- and Site-Dependent Life-Cycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> Thermal <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment<br />

Processes, Dissertation submitted to the Swiss Federal Institute <strong>of</strong> Technology.<br />

1248 No damage costs are given for HCl and HF although emissions <strong>of</strong> these pollutants are limited by<br />

the WID.


Table 63-13: Air Quality Externalities from Incineration Facilities<br />

1005<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

High High Externalities Externalities ( (€ (<br />

€ / / tonne tonne<br />

tonne<br />

input input input to to facility)<br />

facility)<br />

Meets Meets WID WID<br />

Out Out-performs performs<br />

WID<br />

WID<br />

Low Low Externalities Externalities ( (€ (<br />

€ / / tonne tonne<br />

tonne<br />

input input to to facility)<br />

facility)<br />

Meets Meets WID WID<br />

Out Out-performs performs<br />

WID WID<br />

WID<br />

PM10 / dust €3.17 €0.05 €1.13 €0.02<br />

Dioxin 1 €0.00 €0.00 €0.00 €0.00<br />

NOx €16.32 €2.99 €5.64 €1.03<br />

SO2 €5.28 €0.17 €1.81 €0.06<br />

CO 2 €0.00 €0.00 €0.00 €0.00<br />

NMVOC €0.15 €0.00 €0.05 €0.00<br />

Total heavy metal €0.29 €0.06 €0.29 €0.06<br />

Total - direct process €25.21 €3.29 €8.92 €1.18<br />

Energy use at facility 3 €9.45 €9.45 €3.27 €3.27<br />

Avoided emissions 4 - €2.78 - €2.78 - €0.96 - €0.96<br />

Notes<br />

1. The impacts associated with dioxin emissions are negligible from well managed<br />

incineration facilities<br />

2. Damage costs for CO are very low, resulting in low external costs for this pollutant<br />

3. Over 80% <strong>of</strong> these emissions result from the combustion <strong>of</strong> diesel<br />

4. Avoided emissions resulting from electricity generation<br />

63.4 MBT - Aerobic Stabilisation Systems<br />

63.4.1 Climate Change Impacts <strong>of</strong> Aerobic Stabilisation Systems<br />

The approach for modelling the impacts <strong>of</strong> stabilisation processes draws upon work<br />

by Eunomia on behalf <strong>of</strong> WRAP, which was based upon a raft <strong>of</strong> published<br />

research. 1249 The body <strong>of</strong> research included work by Baky and Eriksson, Sonneson,<br />

1249 K. Schleiss (1999) Grüngutbewirtschaftung im Kanton Zürich aus betriebswirtschlaftlicher und<br />

ökologischer Sicht: Situationsanalyse, Szenarioanalyse, ökonomische und ökologische Bewertung<br />

sowie Synthese mit MAUT, Dissertation ETH No 13,746, 1999; Eunomia Research & Consulting,<br />

Scuola Agraria del Parco di Monza, HDRA Consultants, ZREU and LDK ECO on behalf <strong>of</strong> ECOTEC<br />

Research & Consulting (2002) Economic Analysis <strong>of</strong> Options for Managing Biodegradable Municipal<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>, Final Report to the European Commission; D.P. Komilis and R.K. Ham (2004) Life-Cycle<br />

Inventory <strong>of</strong> Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> and Yard <strong>Waste</strong> Windrow Composting in the United States, Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Environmental Engineering, 130(11), pp.1390-1400; A. Baky and O. Eriksson (2003) Systems<br />

Analysis <strong>of</strong> Organic <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in Denmark, Environmental Project No. 822, Copenhagen:


and Komilis and Ham, all <strong>of</strong> whom investigated the link between the biochemical<br />

composition <strong>of</strong> the waste and the release <strong>of</strong> CO2 within composting processes. This<br />

research, together with data sourced from technology suppliers, was used to model<br />

the degradation <strong>of</strong> carbon fractions within our model.<br />

Table 63-14 outlines the key assumptions within the model for stabilisation<br />

processes.<br />

Table 63-14: Assumptions for Stabilisation Process<br />

Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

Residence time 10 weeks<br />

Electricity requirement 50 kWh / t input<br />

Diesel use by process 1 l / t input<br />

CH4 emissions from process 0.01 kg / t input<br />

N2O emissions from process 0.04 kg / t input<br />

Recovery rate for ferrous metals 80%<br />

Recovery rate for non ferrous metals 80%<br />

Recovery rate for plastics 70%<br />

Our assumptions for the landfill <strong>of</strong> pre-treated (stabilised) material have been<br />

previously discussed in Section 63.2.1.5.<br />

63.4.2 Air Quality Impacts<br />

To minimise emissions from the stabilisation process, air circulation and/or a<br />

controlled air supply system is usually installed. Bi<strong>of</strong>ilters are typically used to reduce<br />

emissions <strong>of</strong> NMVOC and other organic pollutants emanating from the stabilisation<br />

process itself. These involve the use <strong>of</strong> microorganisms to biologically degrade the<br />

pollutants.<br />

In the biological treatment step, the material is assumed to undergo an aerobic<br />

stabilisation. The emissions are derived from Hellweg et al, these being derived in<br />

turn from work by Wahlmann et al. 1250<br />

The principal air quality impacts are:<br />

Danish EPA; U. Sonesson (1996) Modelling <strong>of</strong> the Compost and Transport Process in the ORWARE<br />

Simulation Model, Report 214, Swedish University <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Sciences (SLU), <strong>Department</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

Agricultural Engineering, Uppsala Sweden.<br />

1250 Stefanie Hellweg, Gabor Doka, Goran Finnvenden and Konrad Hungerbuhler (2003) Ecology:<br />

Which Technologies Perform Best?, in Christian Ludwig, Stefanie Hellweg and Samuel Stucki (eds)<br />

(2003) Municipal Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong>: Strategies and Technologies for Sustainable Solutions,<br />

London: Springer.<br />

1006<br />

29/09/09


1007<br />

1. Energy used within the treatment process, giving rise to damage costs <strong>of</strong><br />

€3.08 under the high externalities (mostly from the use <strong>of</strong> diesel);<br />

2. Total direct emissions from the stabilisation process and the landfilling <strong>of</strong> the<br />

residues result in external damage costs <strong>of</strong> €0.47 under the high externalities<br />

(emissions <strong>of</strong> NMVOCs from stabilisation account for most <strong>of</strong> this impact).<br />

63.5 MBT Aerobic Biodrying Systems<br />

63.5.1 Climate Change Impacts <strong>of</strong> MBT Aerobic Biodrying Systems<br />

Biodrying systems involve the application <strong>of</strong> intensive heat to the waste to ensure the<br />

removal <strong>of</strong> moisture prior to it being used as fuel. During this process degradation <strong>of</strong><br />

some <strong>of</strong> the carbon fractions will occur as a result <strong>of</strong> the increase in temperature but<br />

the amount <strong>of</strong> degradation is relatively limited in comparison that occurring during<br />

aerobic decomposition (stabilisation) processes.<br />

Emissions <strong>of</strong> CO2 are calculated from the carbon loss estimated over a two week<br />

period. The figures for carbon loss are estimated by ourselves for each <strong>of</strong> the<br />

components <strong>of</strong> the waste stream. We have been able to correlate these estimates<br />

over several years using an analysis <strong>of</strong> data from technology suppliers.<br />

The central aim <strong>of</strong> biodrying processes is to produce a fuel. A reject stream is also<br />

produced, which is assumed to be stabilised before being sent to landfill, using the<br />

process previously described in Section 0.<br />

Table 63-15 outlines key assumptions used to model the biodrying phase.<br />

Our assumptions regarding the nature <strong>of</strong> the SRF produced are detailed in Table<br />

63-16.<br />

Our analysis considers two uses for the output from the biodrying process:<br />

1. The SRF is combusted at a dedicated incineration facility generating electricity<br />

as has been previously described in Section 63.3.<br />

2. The SRF is combusted at a cement kiln where it is assumed to displace the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> coal. We assume a 90% substitution ratio for the fuel displacement,<br />

and that the coal would otherwise emit 0.37 kg CO2 equivalent per kWh <strong>of</strong><br />

energy generated.<br />

Our assumptions for the landfill <strong>of</strong> pre-treated (stabilised) material have been<br />

previously discussed in Section 63.2.1.5.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 63-15: Assumed Used for Modelling Biodrying Phase<br />

Parameter Parameter Parameter<br />

Ass Assumption Ass umption<br />

Residence time in biodrying phase 12 days<br />

Residence time <strong>of</strong> rejects in maturation (stabilisation) phase 7 weeks<br />

Electricity requirement 1 40 kWh / t input<br />

Diesel use by process 1 0.5 l / t input<br />

CH4 emissions from process 2 0.01 kg / t input<br />

N20 emissions from process 2 0.02 kg / t input<br />

Recovery rate for ferrous metals 80%<br />

Recovery rate for non-ferrous metals 80%<br />

Recovery rates for plastics 70%<br />

Notes:<br />

1. Per tonne input to the MBT facility.<br />

2. Per tonne input to the biodrying process.<br />

Table 63-16: Model Parameters for Residual <strong>Waste</strong> to SRF<br />

Parameter Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

Amount <strong>of</strong> SRF produced by biodrying process (per tonne to facility) 0.4 tonnes<br />

Energy content <strong>of</strong> SRF (lower heating value as received) 16.5 MJ / kg<br />

% <strong>of</strong> carbon that is non-fossil 46%<br />

63.5.2 Air Quality Impacts <strong>of</strong> Aerobic Biodrying Systems<br />

As is the case with the aerobic stabilisation systems, biodrying plant typically install<br />

controlled air supply systems and bi<strong>of</strong>ilters to minimise the impact <strong>of</strong> organic<br />

pollutants emanating from the aerobic degradation process. Non-GHG air emissions<br />

are calculated from work undertaken for the Austrian Umweltbundesamt, though we<br />

have adapted these over time based on more up to date data. 1251 These are<br />

dependent upon the choice <strong>of</strong> emissions abatement equipment at the plant (each<br />

modelled in the study). There are three key options which the study addressed:<br />

1008<br />

� Basic bi<strong>of</strong>ilter;<br />

1251 Uwe Lahl, Barbara Zeschmar-Lahl and Thomas Angerer (2000) Entwicklungspotentiale der<br />

Mechanisch-biologischen Abfallbehandlung: Eine Ökologische Analyse, Vienna: Umweltbundesamt,<br />

June 2000.<br />

29/09/09


1009<br />

� Optimised bi<strong>of</strong>ilter; and<br />

� Thermal filter.<br />

The choice <strong>of</strong> abatement equipment determines the level <strong>of</strong> removal <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

gases prior to their emission to the atmosphere. It also determines the level <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

use in the process (especially relevant for the thermal filter option).<br />

We have assumed that MBT facilities operate with optimised bi<strong>of</strong>ilters. The<br />

requirement, in Germany, to deploy regenerative thermal oxidation (or other)<br />

processes to crack remaining VOCs from the exhaust gas appears, in our view, to be<br />

unjustifiable when the additional benefits are set against the additional energy<br />

demand implied by the process. 1252<br />

Pollution abatement techniques employed at incineration facilities have been<br />

previously discussed in Section 63.3.2. Again we have assumed two types <strong>of</strong> facilities<br />

– one which complies with the WID, and a second which has installed additional<br />

abatement equipment and therefore exceeds the requirements <strong>of</strong> the WID. Our<br />

assumptions for the landfill <strong>of</strong> pre-treated (stabilised) material have been previously<br />

discussed in Section 63.2.1.5.<br />

Our analysis considers two uses for the output from the biodrying process:<br />

1. The SRF is combusted at a dedicated incineration facility generating electricity<br />

as has been previously described in Section 63.3.<br />

2. The SRF is combusted at a cement kiln where it is assumed to displace the<br />

use <strong>of</strong> coal. We assume a 90% substitution ratio for the fuel displacement,<br />

and that the coal would otherwise emit 0.37 kg CO2 equivalent per kWh <strong>of</strong><br />

energy generated.<br />

Our assumptions for the landfill <strong>of</strong> pre-treated (stabilised) material have been<br />

previously discussed in Section 63.2.1.5.<br />

The principal air quality impacts are:<br />

1. Energy used within the treatment process, giving rise to damage costs <strong>of</strong><br />

€6.42 under high externalities or €2.22 assuming low external costs. Most <strong>of</strong><br />

this impact arises from the use <strong>of</strong> diesel within the facility. 1253<br />

2. Where the SRF is sent to an incinerator, total emissions from direct treatment<br />

processes (including the biodrying and stabilisation components and the<br />

combustion <strong>of</strong> SRF as well as the landfilling <strong>of</strong> residues) result in external<br />

damage costs <strong>of</strong> €10.64 under the higher externalities or €3.69 assuming low<br />

1252 Bi<strong>of</strong>ilters themselves are sources <strong>of</strong> VOCs, though typically <strong>of</strong> less benign species than the type<br />

one seeks to remove from exhaust gases. To assume that all VOCs are equally detrimental to air<br />

quality and health is to misunderstand the problem, and although RTO deployment will further reduce<br />

VOC emissions, (as we show within this review) it tends to do so at considerable additional cost from<br />

the perspective <strong>of</strong> climate change.<br />

1253 The additional diesel consumption reflects that used within the incineration <strong>of</strong> SRF. Assumptions<br />

used here are the same (on a per tonne basis) as for the incineration <strong>of</strong> untreated wastes.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


1010<br />

29/09/09<br />

external costs. Emissions associated with the combustion <strong>of</strong> SRF account for<br />

over 90% <strong>of</strong> these impacts. The total direct impact is reduced to €3.27 and<br />

€1.15 for the high and low costs respectively if the incinerator significantly outperforms<br />

the WID (as previously discussed in Section 63.3.2).<br />

3. The combustion <strong>of</strong> SRF in an incinerator is assumed to avoid emissions <strong>of</strong><br />

€1.67 associated with the generation <strong>of</strong> electricity assuming high external<br />

costs or €0.58 if the lower external costs are applied.<br />

4. Where the SRF is sent to a cement kiln, external damage costs relating to the<br />

total combustion related impacts are €8.11. These damages are assumed to<br />

occur as a result <strong>of</strong> the 90% substitution ratio for SRF and coal, based on the<br />

higher emissions that occur in the cement kiln. 1254<br />

63.6 Summary <strong>of</strong> Results, Residual <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Table 63-17 and Table 63-18 summarise the results <strong>of</strong> our analysis, detailing the<br />

external costs associated with the different waste treatment technologies under the<br />

high and low external costs respectively. Climate change impacts are highly<br />

significant for landfill whilst the air quality impacts are relatively more significant for<br />

incineration.<br />

Table 63-17: Results with High External Costs<br />

Climate Climate<br />

Climate<br />

Change<br />

Change<br />

Air Air Quality Quality Total<br />

Total<br />

Landfill (50% gas capture) €80.66 €5.88 €86.54<br />

Landfill (20% gas capture) €123.62 €5.52 €129.14<br />

Incineration (meets WID) €26.24 €31.87 €58.11<br />

Incineration (out-performs WID) €26.24 €9.96 €36.20<br />

MBT aerobic biodrying / incineration €22.94 €15.38 €38.32<br />

MBT aerobic stabilisation €18.82 €3.55 €22.37<br />

MBT aerobic biodrying / cement kiln €9.16 €11.53 €20.70<br />

MBT aerobic biodrying (50% gas capture) €26.67 €15.38 €42.05<br />

MBT aerobic biodrying (out-performs WID) €22.83 €8.02 €30.85<br />

MBT aerobic stabilisation (50% gas capture) €35.84 €3.55 €39.39<br />

1254 The <strong>Waste</strong> Incineration Directive allows higher emissions limits for cement kilns co-incinerating<br />

waste than those imposed on dedicated incineration facilities.


Table 63-18: Results with Low External Costs<br />

1011<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Climate<br />

Climate<br />

Change<br />

Change<br />

Air Air Quality Quality Total Total<br />

Total<br />

Landfill (50% gas capture) €66.86 €2.07 €68.94<br />

Landfill (20% gas capture) €102.48 €2.35 €104.83<br />

Incineration (meets WID) €21.75 €11.23 €32.98<br />

Incineration (out-performs WID) €21.75 €3.49 €25.24<br />

MBT aerobic biodrying / incineration €18.98 €5.33 €24.31<br />

MBT aerobic stabilisation €15.38 €1.23 €16.61<br />

MBT aerobic biodrying / cement kiln €7.48 €4.00 €11.48<br />

MBT aerobic biodrying (50% gas capture) €22.07 €5.33 €27.40<br />

MBT aerobic biodrying (out-performs WID) €18.98 €6.99 €25.97<br />

MBT aerobic stabilisation (50% gas capture) €28.67 €1.23 €29.90<br />

63.7 Dry Recycling<br />

In producing virgin products (i.e. products made from non-recycled materials) it is<br />

inevitable that raw materials will be required. These raw materials may be mined from<br />

the ground or extracted from forests (in the case <strong>of</strong> paper/wood manufacture).<br />

Additional resources, in the form <strong>of</strong> the energy used for the mining or paper<br />

manufacture, for example, will also be required. This resource requirement results in<br />

emissions to air that have consequences for climate change and for local air quality.<br />

If a product is manufactured from recycled materials, the requirement for raw<br />

materials is diminished. This typically reduces the energy used resulting in a reduction<br />

in emissions during the manufacturing process. Emissions are therefore said to have<br />

been ‘avoided’ as a result <strong>of</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> the recycled materials.<br />

Although the concept <strong>of</strong> reduced emissions from recycling/reprocessing is well<br />

understood, there is rather less by way <strong>of</strong> consensus as to the actual quantity <strong>of</strong> the<br />

savings <strong>of</strong>fered by recycling. In recent years, there has been focus on evidence from<br />

life cycle assessment (LCA) studies, which have sought to estimate the entire<br />

environmental impact <strong>of</strong> waste management systems. However, LCA studies are<br />

sensitive to a range <strong>of</strong> issues such as starting assumptions and boundary setting,<br />

which lead to very different results for similar systems, depending on the<br />

methodology involved. The outcome <strong>of</strong> the analysis is dependent upon a range <strong>of</strong><br />

assumptions, which include:<br />

� Energy sources used for primary and secondary production from raw materials;<br />

� The collection system for the recovered materials;<br />

� Energy requirements for reprocessing the recycled material;


1012<br />

� Emissions associated with disposal <strong>of</strong> the product (for the virgin production<br />

system, where it is assumed that the product is not recycled at the end <strong>of</strong> its<br />

life).<br />

The range <strong>of</strong> possible re-processing technologies and the different methodologies<br />

employed for calculating emissions reductions has resulted in a wide range <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>fsets<br />

being attributed with respect to the recycling <strong>of</strong> the same type <strong>of</strong> material. This is<br />

particularly the case with regard to the climate change impacts, which have been<br />

more widely studied.<br />

63.7.1 Climate Change Impacts<br />

Table 63-19 summarises some <strong>of</strong> the evidence from the literature with regard to the<br />

climate change impacts associated with recycling the most commonly collected<br />

materials. Best and worst case scenarios are presented, along with typical values.<br />

The table identifies the key assumptions within the reviewed studies that result in the<br />

calculation <strong>of</strong> the more extreme values associated with the best and worst cases. The<br />

table shows that recycling typically results in avoided greenhouse gas emissions for<br />

all <strong>of</strong> those materials commonly recycled.<br />

The results presented in Table 63-19 show that aluminium recycling results in the<br />

most significant emissions savings where impacts are considered on the basis <strong>of</strong> one<br />

tonne <strong>of</strong> material recycled, largely as a result <strong>of</strong> the significant energy expenditure<br />

involved in manufacturing the product from virgin materials. The damage costs<br />

associated with the typical values presented in Table 63-19 are shown in Table<br />

63-20, under both the high and low externalities.<br />

63.7.2 Air Quality Impacts<br />

Section 63.7.1 confirms that the greenhouse gas implications <strong>of</strong> recycling materials<br />

have been considered by a range <strong>of</strong> studies. Far less data is available with respect to<br />

the air quality impacts associated with recycling the same products.<br />

One study that did consider these impacts is the international review <strong>of</strong> the<br />

environmental benefits <strong>of</strong> recycling undertaken by WRAP. The study included a range<br />

<strong>of</strong> different re-processing technologies for different materials being recycled across<br />

various countries. However the majority <strong>of</strong> studies included within the review focused<br />

on the climate change impacts <strong>of</strong> recycling (this data is included within Table 63-19).<br />

Far less information is available with respect to the air quality impacts associated<br />

with these processes, and what is available is limited to emissions <strong>of</strong> NOx and SOx<br />

only.<br />

29/09/09


Table 63-19: Emissions Associated with Recycling Materials<br />

Material Material Emissions Emissions t t CO CO2 CO equ<br />

equ<br />

(per (per tonne tonne <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> waste)<br />

waste)<br />

Paper<br />

Steel<br />

Aluminium<br />

Plastic<br />

Glass<br />

Textiles<br />

1013<br />

Best -3.5<br />

Worst 1.1<br />

Typical Typical -0.6 0.6<br />

Best -3.1<br />

Worst 1.5<br />

Typical Typical -1.2 1.2<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Critic Critical Critic al assumptions<br />

assumptions<br />

Inclusion <strong>of</strong> carbon sequestration; substantial avoided<br />

emissions from landfill / wood energy not used<br />

Incineration <strong>of</strong> paper; use <strong>of</strong> wood energy to produce<br />

virgin paper<br />

Recycling process uses similar / less carbon intensive<br />

energy generation process; relatively high energy use in<br />

virgin manufacturing process<br />

Recycling process uses a more carbon intensive energy<br />

generation process<br />

Best -15.1 Higher energy use in virgin manufacturing process<br />

Worst 1.5 High recovery efficiency from incinerator residues<br />

Typical Typical -9.17 9.17<br />

Best -4.1<br />

Worst 3.8<br />

Typical Typical -1.4<br />

Best -2.5<br />

Recycled is substituted for virgin on 1:1 basis; no hot<br />

water washing required<br />

Compared to incineration; hot water washing and poorer<br />

substitution ratio<br />

Recycled glass system produced with low carbon<br />

intensive source <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

Worst 0.5 Open loop processes (use <strong>of</strong> glass as aggregate)<br />

Typical Typical -0.3 0.3 0.3<br />

Best -7.9 .9<br />

Worst -0.93 0.93<br />

Typical Typical -3.03 3.03<br />

These tend to be associated with natural fibres such as<br />

wool – presumably, synthetic fibres might tend towards<br />

values akin to those for plastic, or lower<br />

Notes Notes: Notes : The negative values here represent emissions ‘avoided’ or saved as a result <strong>of</strong> recycling<br />

Typical emissions for paper recycling have been adjusted to remove the element associated<br />

with avoided disposal.<br />

Sources: WRAP (2006) Environmental Benefits <strong>of</strong> Recycling: An <strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> Life cycle<br />

Comparisons for Key Materials in the UK Recycling Sector, Banbury: Oxon, WRAP, May 2006; AEA<br />

Technology (2001) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options and Climate Change: Final Report, European<br />

Commission: DG Environment, July 2001; USEPA (2006) Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Greenhouse<br />

Gases: A Life-Cycle Assessment <strong>of</strong> Emissions and Sinks, 3 rd Edition, September 2006; ERM (2006)<br />

Carbon Balances and Energy Impacts <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Management</strong> <strong>of</strong> UK <strong>Waste</strong>s, Final Report for Defra,<br />

December 2006; ERM (2006) Impact <strong>of</strong> Energy from <strong>Waste</strong> and Recycling <strong>Policy</strong> on UK Greenhouse<br />

Gas Emissions, Final Report for Defra, January 2006; European Aluminium Association (2008)<br />

Environmental Pr<strong>of</strong>ile Report for the European Aluminium Industry: Life Cycle Inventory Data for<br />

Aluminium Production and Transformation Processes in Europe, April 2008; Enviros (2003) Glass<br />

Recycling – Life Cycle Carbon Dioxide Emissions, internal report for the British Glass Public Affairs<br />

Committee


Table 63-20: External Costs <strong>of</strong> Dry Recycling – Climate Change Impacts<br />

Material<br />

Material<br />

1014<br />

29/09/09<br />

External External Costs Costs – Climate Climate Change Change Impacts<br />

Impacts<br />

High High externalities externalities<br />

Low Low Low externalities<br />

externalities<br />

Paper - € 19.93 - € 16.52<br />

Steel - € 38.57 - € 31.97<br />

Aluminium - € 294.69 - € 244.29<br />

Plastic - € 44.99 - € 37.30<br />

Glass - € 9.64 - € 7.99<br />

Textiles -€ 97.38 -€ 80.72<br />

Notes<br />

Analysis uses the typical values presented in Table 63-19 together with the external costs<br />

presented<br />

Data regarding the other air emissions associated with recycling materials is also<br />

available within the Environment Agency’s life-cycle tool for waste management<br />

processes, WRATE. 1255 These impacts are calculated using the Swiss life-cycle<br />

database Ecoinvent. 1256 The inventory produced by WRATE presents data on a much<br />

wider range <strong>of</strong> air emissions than is considered within the WRAP review.<br />

Impacts calculated using WRATE are based on the differential (in air quality terms)<br />

between products manufactured using virgin materials, and those manufactured from<br />

recycled input. In contrast, the methodology used by WRAP also considers emissions<br />

avoided as a result <strong>of</strong> recycled material not being sent for disposal.<br />

Air quality impacts associated with manufacturing and re-processing will not have a<br />

direct impact on Irish air quality where both <strong>of</strong> these activities takes place overseas.<br />

Emissions avoided as a result <strong>of</strong> recycled material not being sent for disposal will,<br />

however, directly affect Irish air quality. The principal avoided disposal emissions are<br />

presented in Table 63-21. These impacts are calculated using the same methodology<br />

as for calculating the impacts associated with residual waste.<br />

Table 63-22 shows the air quality impacts associated with the re-processing part <strong>of</strong><br />

the system (i.e. where a product is manufactured from recycled input). In many cases<br />

the production <strong>of</strong> goods from recycled materials results in reduced air quality burdens<br />

in comparison to the manufacture <strong>of</strong> the same product from raw materials. Much <strong>of</strong><br />

this reduction results from the lower energy requirements associated with the use <strong>of</strong><br />

recycled input in manufacturing processes (this is particularly the case for non ferrous<br />

1255 Available from http://www.environment-agency.gov.uk/research/commercial/102929.aspx<br />

1256 Ecoinvent (2004) Ecoinvent Data v1.1, Final Reports Ecoinvent 2000, No. 1-15, Swiss Centre for<br />

Life Cycle Inventories, Dubendorf, 2004


metal, the production <strong>of</strong> which consumes significant quantities <strong>of</strong> energy). However,<br />

such emissions reductions will not have a direct impact on Irish air quality, since a<br />

significant proportion <strong>of</strong> the manufacturing <strong>of</strong> these products (whether made from<br />

virgin or recycled input) occurs overseas.<br />

Table 63-21: Avoided Disposal Emissions (Non Greenhouse Gas Emissions)<br />

Material(s)<br />

Material(s)<br />

1015<br />

Disposal<br />

Disposal<br />

method<br />

method<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Principal Principal avoided avoided air air emissions (per tonne tonne <strong>of</strong><br />

material aterial disposed at at facility)<br />

Paper Landfill 0.9 kg ammonia; 0.7 kg NOx<br />

Plastic, metals, glass Landfill 0.1 kg NOx (diesel use)<br />

Paper Incineration 1.5 kg NOx; 0.3 kg SOx; 0.1 kg particulates<br />

Plastic Incineration 1.1 kg NOx; 0.3 kg SOx; 0.1 kg particulates<br />

Glass, metals Incineration 1.7 kg NOx; 0.3 kg SOx; 0.1 kg particulates<br />

Paper Biodrying 0.8 kg NOx; 0.2 kg SOx; 0.1 kg particulates<br />

Plastic Biodrying 0.3 kg NOx; 0.1 kg SOx<br />

Glass Biodrying 0.4 kg NOx; 0.1 kg SOx<br />

Metals Biodrying 0.4 kg NOx; 0.1 kg SOx<br />

Paper Stabilisation 0.2 kg NMVOC; 0.2 kg NOx (energy use)<br />

Plastic Stabilisation 0.2 kg NOx (energy use)<br />

Glass Stabilisation 0.2 kg NOx (energy use)<br />

Metals Stabilisation 0.2 kg NOx (energy use)<br />

Notes<br />

Plastic has a higher calorific value than the other materials so more NOx emissions are<br />

avoided through energy generation<br />

Table 63-23 presents damage costs for the air quality impacts associated with dry<br />

recycling. The table separately identifies impacts resulting from the avoided disposal<br />

<strong>of</strong> the material, and those associated with re-processing impacts.


Table 63-22: Avoided Emissions Recycling – Re-processing Impacts<br />

Pollutant<br />

Pollutant<br />

1016<br />

29/09/09<br />

Avoided Avoided emissions emissions emissions through through recycling recycling (kg (kg polluta pollutant polluta polluta nt / t t recyclate)<br />

recyclate)<br />

Paper Paper Paper Dense Dense plastic plastic Glass<br />

Glass<br />

Ferrous<br />

Ferrous<br />

metal<br />

metal<br />

Non Non ferrous ferrous<br />

ferrous<br />

metal<br />

metal<br />

NH3 0.01 -0.01 0.16 0.07 0.15<br />

VOCs 0.04 3.54 0.02 0.25 2.20<br />

PM2.5 0.10 0.40 0.19 0.78 4.62<br />

SOx 0.01 -0.01 0.03 0.01 0.01<br />

NOx 0.92 5.68 0.30 2.70 18.00<br />

Cd 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Cr 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Hg 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Ni 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Pb 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.04<br />

Dioxin 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

As 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Notes<br />

The negative numbers in the above table represent an additional air quality impact occurring<br />

as a result <strong>of</strong> re-processing (in comparison to a situation where the product is manufactured<br />

from virgin input)<br />

Source: WRATE<br />

Table 63-23: Damage Costs – Air Quality Impacts <strong>of</strong> Recycling<br />

Paper Paper Plastics Plastics Glass<br />

Glass<br />

Ferrous Ferrous<br />

Ferrous<br />

metal<br />

metal<br />

Non Non<br />

Non<br />

ferrous<br />

ferrous<br />

metal metal<br />

metal<br />

Re-processing impacts - € 17.95 - € 108.05 - € 16.12 - € 81.83 - € 453.29<br />

Notes<br />

Re-processing impacts are calculated using inventory data from WRATE.<br />

63.8 Composting Processes<br />

This section considers the environmental impacts associated with two types <strong>of</strong><br />

composting process<br />

1. Windrow (or open) composting systems;<br />

2. In vessel (or enclosed) composting systems.


The two processes have similar environmental impacts. Key differences between the<br />

two are:<br />

1017<br />

� The use <strong>of</strong> bi<strong>of</strong>ilters in the in-vessel system to reduce ammonia (NH3) and VOC<br />

emissions occurring during the process, resulting in additional N2O emissions;<br />

� The nature <strong>of</strong> energy consumption (in vessel systems require the use <strong>of</strong> some<br />

electricity, whilst the windrow facilities use more diesel).<br />

The sections that follow discuss the environmental impacts <strong>of</strong> composting processes<br />

with respect to air emissions <strong>of</strong> relevance to climate change and air quality. The use<br />

<strong>of</strong> the compost results in other environmental benefits such as a reduction in the<br />

requirement for the use <strong>of</strong> synthetic fertilisers. These benefits - relating to reductions<br />

in soil and water pollution, as well as air pollution - are discussed in Section 63.8.4.<br />

A summary <strong>of</strong> the damage costs associated with composting processes is provided in<br />

Section 63.8.5.<br />

63.8.1 Nitrogenous Emissions from Composting Processes<br />

Nitrogenous emissions from composting processes impact on both climate change<br />

and air quality. The NH3 emissions are determined by the quantity <strong>of</strong> ammonium ions,<br />

urea, and organically bound nitrogen. The pH value, temperature, ventilation, and the<br />

C/N-relation constitute other influencing factors. An increase in the pH value, higher<br />

temperature, or better ventilation may all lead to greater emissions. High C/N<br />

relations cause NH3 emissions to diminish. 1257<br />

Nitrous oxide emissions are also determined by temperature, ventilation, nitrogen<br />

content, the C/N relation, and other factors. 1258 Maximum N2O formation rates are<br />

observed if the supply <strong>of</strong> oxygen during decomposition is insufficient. This may occur,<br />

for example, if the partial pressure <strong>of</strong> oxygen in the rotting material drops to zero due<br />

to very high rates <strong>of</strong> biological activity. 1259<br />

1257 K. Csehi, J. Beck and T. Jungbluth (1996) Emissionen bei der Mietenkompostierung tierischer<br />

Exkremente. Landtechnik 51, S. 218-219; K. Csehi (1977) Ammoniakemission bei der Kompostierung<br />

tierischer Exkremente in Mieten und Kompostqualität. Diss. Universität Hohenheim 1977, MEG-<br />

Forschungsbericht 311, 156 S; T. Maeda and J. Matsuda (1997) Ammonia Emissions from Composting<br />

Livestock Manure (Ammoniakemissionen bei der Mistkompostierung), in A. M. Voermanns and G.<br />

Montney (eds.) (1997) Ammonia and Odour Control from Animal Production Facilities (Ammoniak- und<br />

Geruchskontrolle aus Tierproduktionsanlagen), Proceedings I, Vinkeloord, Niederlande, 6.-10. 10.<br />

1997, S. 145-153.<br />

1258 L. Hüther (1999) Entwicklung Analytischer Methoden und Untersuchung von Einflußfaktoren auf<br />

Ammoniak-, Methan- und Distickst<strong>of</strong>fmonoxidemissionen aus Flüssig- und Festmist.<br />

Landbauforschung Völkenrode, Sonderheft 200, Braunschweig (FAL) 1999, 225 S.<br />

1259 H. J. Hellebrand (1998) Emission <strong>of</strong> Nitrous Oxide and Other Trace Gases During Composting <strong>of</strong><br />

Grass and Green <strong>Waste</strong> (Emission von Lachgas und anderen Spurengasen während der<br />

Grüngutkompostierung). J. Agric. Engng Res. 69, S. 365-375; S. Zhou, H. Zaeid, and H. Van den Weghe<br />

(1999) Kompostierung tierischer Exkremente - Einfluß der Sauerst<strong>of</strong>fkonzentration auf<br />

Reaktionskinetik und Emissionsverhalten, Agrartechnische Forschung 5, S. 2-10<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Aeration and the C:N ratio are believed to have an important effect on the nitrogen<br />

conversion processes. Where composting processes have included manures,<br />

intensive aeration in connection with low C-content has been shown to give rise to<br />

nitrite accumulation in slurry (up to 33% <strong>of</strong> the total nitrogen content) and incomplete<br />

ammonium oxidation. Low ventilation rates and sufficient carbon supply support the<br />

formation <strong>of</strong> nitrous oxide during nitrification and denitrification processes.<br />

Gronauer et al suggest that around 12% <strong>of</strong> total nitrogen escapes from the material in<br />

the form <strong>of</strong> ammonia. 1260 This gave a figure <strong>of</strong> 0.53kg/tonne waste in raw gas, but<br />

0.0264kg per tonne waste when the air is passed through a bi<strong>of</strong>ilter. Gronauer et al<br />

also assumed that 0.15kg N2O per tonne waste would be emitted.<br />

One Swedish study assumed the nitrogen leakage to air was 7.5% <strong>of</strong> the nitrogen<br />

content <strong>of</strong> the feedstock. 1261 Of this leakage, it was assumed 89% was emitted as<br />

NH3, 9% as N2O and 2% N2. The study for the Danish EPA assumed that <strong>of</strong> the total<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> nitrogen lost as gaseous emission, 98 % was volatilised as NH3, 0.5 % as<br />

N2O and 1.5 % as N2 (the figures relate to raw gas as opposed to gas which has been<br />

scrubbed). 1262<br />

Our analysis assumes nitrogenous emissions from composting processes are as<br />

follows:<br />

1018<br />

� 10% <strong>of</strong> the total nitrogen content <strong>of</strong> the waste is released in some form. Of this<br />

10%, we further assume that:<br />

29/09/09<br />

• 88% is released as NH3;<br />

• 2% is released as N2 (this is not a problem for the environment); and<br />

• 10% is released as N2O.<br />

Whilst the NH3 is released untreated in windrow systems, in vessel systems typically<br />

make use <strong>of</strong> bi<strong>of</strong>ilters to convert much <strong>of</strong> this pollutant to N2O. This is discussed in<br />

the sections that follow.<br />

63.8.2 Climate Change Impacts <strong>of</strong> Composting Processes<br />

Table 63-24 outlines the key assumptions used to model the climate change impacts<br />

<strong>of</strong> composting processes, which were developed in a previous study for WRAP by<br />

1260 A. Gronauer, M. Helm, H. Schon (1997) Verhafen und Konzepte der Bioabfallkompostierung –<br />

Vergleich – Bewertung – Empfehlungen, Bayerische Landesanstalt fur Landtechnik der TU Munchen-<br />

Weihenstephan<br />

1261 Goran Finnvenden, Jessica Johansson, Per Lind and Asa Moberg (2000) Life Cycle Assessments <strong>of</strong><br />

Energy from Solid <strong>Waste</strong>, Forskningsgruppen for Miljostrategiska Studier, FMS 137, August 2000<br />

1262 B. Gunnarsdotter Beck-Friis (2001) Emissions <strong>of</strong> Ammonia, Nitrous Oxide and Methane during<br />

Composting <strong>of</strong> Organic Household <strong>Waste</strong>, Agraria 266, Doctoral Thesis, SLU, Sweden, sited in A. Baky<br />

and O. Eriksson (2003) Systems Analysis <strong>of</strong> Organic <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> in Denmark, Environmental<br />

Project No. 822, Copenhagen: Danish EPA


Eunomia. 1263 The principal climate change impacts are associated with release <strong>of</strong><br />

biogenic CO2 emissions which are not reported in the majority <strong>of</strong> studies that use a<br />

life-cycle assessment approach to analyse the emissions <strong>of</strong> greenhouse gases. Some<br />

impacts are different depending on the feedstock used within the composting<br />

process. N2O emissions are higher when food waste is composted due to the higher<br />

nitrogen content <strong>of</strong> the feedstock.<br />

Table 63-24: Assumptions Used to Model Composting Processes<br />

Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

CH4 emissions from process 0.816 kg / t input<br />

N2O emissions from process<br />

In vessel (garden waste)<br />

In vessel (food waste)<br />

Windrow<br />

1019<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

0.361 kg / t input<br />

0.477 kg / t input<br />

0.117 kg / t input<br />

Non-degraded carbon (retained in biomass) 30%<br />

Electricity requirement<br />

In vessel<br />

Windrow<br />

Diesel use by process<br />

In vessel<br />

Windrow<br />

40 kWh / t input<br />

0 kWh / t input<br />

0.3 l / t input<br />

1.0 l / t input<br />

Mineralisation rate <strong>of</strong> readily available organic matter 20%<br />

Mineralisation rate <strong>of</strong> stable humus 1%<br />

% <strong>of</strong> organic matter from compost becoming humus 25%<br />

Notes:<br />

1. No action <strong>of</strong> bi<strong>of</strong>ilter is assumed for windrow facilities.<br />

2. A further 0.4 litres <strong>of</strong> diesel is used to spread the compost onto land.<br />

3. The mineralisation rate is the rate at which carbon contained within the organic<br />

matter (or humus) is assumed to become atmospheric CO2.<br />

63.8.3 Air Quality Impacts <strong>of</strong> Composting Processes<br />

Other than the greenhouse gases, the principal emissions to air from composting<br />

processes are:<br />

1. NH3;<br />

2. VOCs;<br />

1263 Eunomia (2006) Managing Biowastes from Households in the UK: Applying Life-cycle Thinking in<br />

the Framework <strong>of</strong> Cost-benefit Analysis, Final report for WRAP, May 2006


1020<br />

3. Bioaerosols<br />

Of these, the first two impacts differ depending on the nature <strong>of</strong> the composting<br />

process. This is discussed in Sections 63.8.3.1 and 63.8.3.2. Bioaerosols are<br />

discussed in Section 63.8.3.3.<br />

63.8.3.1 Air Quality Impacts in Windrow Composting<br />

As was previously indicated in Section 63.8.1, our analysis assumes that 10% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

total nitrogen content <strong>of</strong> the waste is released in some form and that <strong>of</strong> this 10%,<br />

88% is released as NH3 in windrow systems that operate without the use <strong>of</strong> a bi<strong>of</strong>ilter.<br />

This results in NH3 emissions <strong>of</strong> 795 g <strong>of</strong> NH3 per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste to the facility.<br />

Although relatively few studies have investigated emissions <strong>of</strong> VOCs from composting<br />

processes, the UK’s Environment Agency did measure emissions from sites. These<br />

are shown in Table 63-25.<br />

Table 63-25: Emissions <strong>of</strong> VOCs from Monitoring <strong>of</strong> Compost Facilities<br />

Compounds Compounds Detected Detected<br />

g / / tonne tonne <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> MSW<br />

MSW<br />

m,p Xylene [108-38-3; 106-42-3] 0.81<br />

Nonane [111-84-2] 0.44<br />

o Xylene [95-47-6] 0.54<br />

Beta.-Pinene [127-91-3] 3.7<br />

Ocimene [13877-91-3] 3.0<br />

D-Limonene [5989-27-5] 10.5<br />

Undecane [1120-21-4] 2.4<br />

Dodecane [112-40-3] 1.2<br />

Methyl-(methylethyl)-Cyclohexane [99-82-1] 1.5<br />

Total 24.0<br />

Source: Environment Agency (2000) Life Cycle Inventory Development for <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Operations: Composting and Anaerobic Digestion, R&D Project Record P1/392/4<br />

We have used the total Environment Agency figure – <strong>of</strong> 24 g <strong>of</strong> emission per tonne <strong>of</strong><br />

waste to the facility - with regard to the emission <strong>of</strong> VOCs from windrow composting<br />

processes.<br />

63.8.3.2 Air Quality Impacts In Vessel Composting Systems<br />

In in-vessel composting systems, NH3 is usually treated in bi<strong>of</strong>ilters. In bi<strong>of</strong>ilters, the<br />

nitrogen in the ammonia is converted to, in varying proportions, N2, NO and N2O.<br />

One study looking at MBT processes suggests a mass balance for a bi<strong>of</strong>ilter as shown<br />

in Figure 63-1. The figure suggests that, as regards N, for every 500 g <strong>of</strong> N entering<br />

the bi<strong>of</strong>ilter as NH3, an additional 111 g <strong>of</strong> N is emitted as N2O. This would imply a<br />

conversion ratio <strong>of</strong> 22%. On the other hand, the above figure suggests a low overall<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> destruction <strong>of</strong> NH3.<br />

29/09/09


Figure 63-1: N-balance <strong>of</strong> a One Step Bi<strong>of</strong>ilter at the MBP Plant in Bassum, Germany<br />

Source: H. Doedens, C. Cuhls, F. Mönkeberg et al. (1999) Balancing Environmentally Relevant<br />

Chemicals in the Biological Pre-Treatment <strong>of</strong> Residual <strong>Waste</strong> – Phase 2: Emissions, Pollutant Balances<br />

and <strong>Waste</strong> Gas Treatment (in German: Final Report for the German Federal Research Project on<br />

mechanical-biological treatment <strong>of</strong> waste before landfill. Hannover: University, 1999<br />

Trimborn et al conclude that independent from the level <strong>of</strong> NH3 load in the raw gas<br />

ca. 29% <strong>of</strong> the transformed NH3 is released as N2O and ca. 9% to NO. 1264<br />

Amlinger et al assume that: 1265<br />

1021<br />

the continuous aerobic conditions in the bi<strong>of</strong>ilter supports the microbial<br />

oxidation <strong>of</strong> NH4 + to NO2 - . High concentrations <strong>of</strong> NH3 and NO2 - can inhibit<br />

further oxidation to NO3 - (Spector, 1998a,b). NO2 - can be directly denitrified to<br />

NO and N2O. It is likely that caused by a high NH3 - concentration the microbial<br />

community in the bi<strong>of</strong>ilter is shifted in a way that deoxidising, denitrifying<br />

enzymatic activities become predominant.<br />

Literature suggests range <strong>of</strong> removal efficiencies for different compounds using<br />

bi<strong>of</strong>ilters. Vogt et al assumed a removal efficiency <strong>of</strong> 96% for NH3, 50% for methane<br />

and 50% for total organic carbon. Omrani et al site removal efficiencies <strong>of</strong> 97-99% for<br />

a bi<strong>of</strong>ilter using peat, soil and sand, whilst one <strong>of</strong> sawdust, clay and sand achieved<br />

94% abatement. 1266<br />

1264 M. Trimborn, H. Goldbach, J. Clemens, C. Cuhls, A. Breeger (2003) Endbericht zum DBU-<br />

Forschungsvorhaben Reduktion von klimawirksamen Spurengasenin der Abluft von Bi<strong>of</strong>iltern auf<br />

Bioabfallbehandlungsanlagen (AZ: 15052)<br />

1265 F. Amlinger, C. Cuhls and S. Peyr (2007) Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Composting and<br />

Mechanical Biological Treatment, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Research<br />

1266 G. Omrani, M. Safa and L. Ghaghazy (2004) Utilization <strong>of</strong> Bi<strong>of</strong>ilter for Ammonia Elimination in<br />

Composting Plant, Pakistan Journal <strong>of</strong> Biological Sciences, 7, pp2009-2013<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The current analysis assumes that in total, 95% <strong>of</strong> the nitrogen in the NH3 entering<br />

the bi<strong>of</strong>ilter is converted by the action <strong>of</strong> the bi<strong>of</strong>ilter. Of the converted proportion,<br />

25% <strong>of</strong> the nitrogen is assumed to be converted to N2O. We also assume that 50% <strong>of</strong><br />

the VOCs are removed by the action <strong>of</strong> the bi<strong>of</strong>ilter, and that those remaining are not<br />

harmful to health (and therefore no damage cost is associated with their emission).<br />

63.8.3.3 Bioaerosols<br />

Significant recent interest, at least within the UK, has centred on the potential<br />

consequences <strong>of</strong> emissions <strong>of</strong> bioaerosols from composting processes. The<br />

Environment Agency sponsored two studies in the early part <strong>of</strong> the decade. These<br />

studies were reviewed for the Cabinet Office in a paper by Hogg. 1267 That review cast<br />

some doubt upon the conclusions drawn from the research undertaken, notably, the<br />

way in which it was used to influence regulatory guidance, for example, in respect <strong>of</strong><br />

distancing from compost facilities. 1268<br />

Bioaerosols are micro-organisms and other tiny biological particles that are<br />

suspended in air. They are respirable and generally invisible. Dusts are small particles<br />

that are larger than bioaerosols. They are inhalable but not respirable and are visible.<br />

Bioaerosols and dusts can both be produced by the composting process. Surveys<br />

have drawn particular attention to a fungus called Aspergillus fumigatus. It is found<br />

all over the world, especially in soils and in forest litter. It is particularly associated<br />

with the composting process as it is capable <strong>of</strong> degrading cellulose (a carbohydrate<br />

found in plant material) and it is capable <strong>of</strong> surviving at temperatures <strong>of</strong> up to 65°C.<br />

As part <strong>of</strong> its lifecycle, Aspergillus fumigatus produces tiny spores. If inhaled as a<br />

bioaerosol these spores may cause allergies and inflammation, which in certain<br />

individuals can cause serious health disorders such as Asthma, Alveolitus, Mucus<br />

membrane irritation, Chronic Bronchitis and coughs, Gastro-intestinal disorders and<br />

Skin disorders.<br />

Individuals who work at a composting facility – less frequently those who are located<br />

in close proximity to a facility – may be exposed to, and inhale large quantities <strong>of</strong><br />

bioaerosols, particularly when compost is being moved or agitated, To most<br />

individuals, exposure to bioaerosols does not appear to cause significant problems.<br />

However, as with some more conventional pollutants, certain individuals, for example<br />

asthmatics and the immuno-compromised, may suffer adverse health effects after<br />

exposure to bioaerosols.<br />

The number <strong>of</strong> individual organisms necessary to cause a reaction varies according to<br />

the state <strong>of</strong> health <strong>of</strong> the person exposed to them. In the composting process, the<br />

levels encountered can be significantly higher than background levels. Therefore it is<br />

imperative that steps should be taken to protect site operatives and residents in the<br />

surrounding areas. Effective operational management can help to control the<br />

formation <strong>of</strong> bioaerosols and dusts and thus reduce the impacts associated with<br />

these pollutants.<br />

1267 D. Hogg (2002) <strong>Waste</strong> Treatments Mk II: Health Effects, Report for the Strategy Unit.<br />

1268 See Environment Agency (2001) Agency Position on Composting and Health Effects, 2001.<br />

1022<br />

29/09/09


It should be noted that bioaerosols from the composting process contain the same<br />

micro-organisms as ones to which citizens are routinely exposed. They are present<br />

naturally and are essential to the recycling <strong>of</strong> nutrients in our gardens, parks and<br />

countryside.<br />

We have not been able to incorporate the impacts <strong>of</strong> bioaerosol emissions into our<br />

model as no dose-response functions have yet been developed to quantify the<br />

impacts associated with this type <strong>of</strong> pollutant. However the preceding discussion<br />

suggests the environmental and health impacts <strong>of</strong> these emissions should be<br />

minimised with the adoption <strong>of</strong> appropriate operational management techniques.<br />

63.8.4 Benefits Associated with the Use <strong>of</strong> Compost<br />

The use <strong>of</strong> compost is associated with monetised benefits, extending beyond the<br />

realm <strong>of</strong> air pollution to include, amongst others, reductions in water pollution and<br />

improvements to soil quality.<br />

We include within our model the slow release <strong>of</strong> CO2 from the soil after the compost is<br />

added. After 50 years, approximately 13% <strong>of</strong> the initial carbon contained within the<br />

compost remains in the soil.<br />

65% <strong>of</strong> the compost produced is assumed to be used in agriculture. Our model<br />

considers the following benefits associated with the use <strong>of</strong> compost in this way: 1269<br />

1023<br />

� The displacement <strong>of</strong> alternative nutrient sources otherwise applied through<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> synthetic fertiliser, including the avoided external costs <strong>of</strong> fertiliser<br />

manufacture and the avoided energy use associated with this;<br />

� The greenhouse gases avoided from nitrogenous fertiliser applications (i.e.<br />

N2O emissions) and the external costs associated with this;<br />

� Avoided external costs from a reduction in the leaching <strong>of</strong> nitrate (from<br />

nitrogenous fertilisers) into groundwater;<br />

� Avoided external costs associated with process wastewater and<br />

phosphogypsum disposal during the manufacture <strong>of</strong> phosphate fertiliser;<br />

� Avoided energy requirement associated with the mining <strong>of</strong> phosphate rock for<br />

phosphate fertiliser, and the avoided external costs associated with this;<br />

� Avoided external costs through a reduction in the use <strong>of</strong> pesticides; and<br />

� Avoided external costs through a reduction in the use <strong>of</strong> water.<br />

The remaining 35% <strong>of</strong> the compost is assumed to displace the use <strong>of</strong> peat in<br />

horticulture and hobby gardening applications. Here the avoided impacts are the slow<br />

release <strong>of</strong> CO2 from the aerobic degradation <strong>of</strong> peat after its removal from the peat-<br />

1269 For a detailed description <strong>of</strong> the methodology used to calculate these estimates see: Eunomia (2007)<br />

Managing Biowastes from Households in the UK: Applying Life-cycle Thinking in the Framework <strong>of</strong> Cost-benefit<br />

Analysis, Appendices to the Main Report, Report for WRAP, May 2007<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


land. 1270 The use <strong>of</strong> compost in horticulture is also assumed to result in a reduction in<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> pesticides.<br />

Monetised benefits associated with the use <strong>of</strong> compost are presented in Table 63-26.<br />

Table 63-26: Monetised Benefits Associated with the Use <strong>of</strong> Compost<br />

Agriculture<br />

Horticulture<br />

1024<br />

29/09/09<br />

In In vessel vessel Windrow<br />

Windrow<br />

Pesticide reduction - € 3.23 - € 3.93<br />

Nutrient displacement - € 2.84 - € 2.62<br />

Avoided phosphate rock extraction - € 0.76 - € 0.56<br />

Avoided process wastewater disposal - € 0.26 - € 0.19<br />

Avoided water use - € 1.07 - € 1.07<br />

Avoided N-leaching - € 2.31 - € 2.29<br />

Avoided N2O emissions - € 0.18 - € 0.18<br />

Avoided peat extraction - € 0.32 - € 0.32<br />

Pesticide reduction - € 1.74 - € 2.11<br />

Notes<br />

Compost produced from the in vessel process is assumed to result from a mixture <strong>of</strong> 70%<br />

garden waste and 30% food waste.<br />

The results shown in Table 63-26 show damage costs relating to compost produced<br />

in an in vessel system with a feedstock <strong>of</strong> 30% food waste, against compost resulting<br />

from a windrow system that is assumed to treat only garden waste. The differences in<br />

the damage costs result from the different feedstocks assumed to be treated by each<br />

type <strong>of</strong> system. A larger volume <strong>of</strong> compost is produced from a feedstock comprised<br />

<strong>of</strong> 100% garden waste, as garden waste contains less moisture, and more <strong>of</strong> the<br />

lignin-based materials which are resistant to degradation. Against this, compost<br />

produced from a feedstock containing food waste has a higher nutrient content, and<br />

can therefore displace greater quantities <strong>of</strong> nutrient that are assumed to have been<br />

otherwise supplied by the use <strong>of</strong> synthetic fertilisers.<br />

63.8.5 Summary – Damage Costs Associated with Composting Processes<br />

Table 63-27 summarises the damage costs associated with treating source<br />

separated organic wastes in composting systems.<br />

1270 This follows the methodology described in AEA Technology (2001) <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Options and Climate<br />

Change: Final Report, European Commission: DG Environment, July 2001


Table 63-27: Summary <strong>of</strong> Damage Costs – Composting Systems<br />

1025<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Damage Damage costs, costs, € per tonne <strong>of</strong> input to process process<br />

In In vessel vessel<br />

Windrow<br />

Windrow<br />

High High Low Low Low High High Low<br />

Low<br />

Climate Change €14.59 €12.21 €14.89 €12.44<br />

Air Quality €2.76 €0.96 €9.02 €3.16<br />

Benefits – use <strong>of</strong> compost - €12.71 - €11.68 - €13.27 - €12.36<br />

TOTALS €4.63 €1.49 €10.64 €3.24<br />

Notes<br />

The feedstock for the in vessel composting system is assumed to comprise <strong>of</strong> 70%<br />

garden waste and 30% food waste.<br />

63.9 Anaerobic Digestion <strong>of</strong> Food <strong>Waste</strong><br />

The environmental impacts associated with the anaerobic digestion (AD) <strong>of</strong> food<br />

waste depend in part on how the biogas produced by the process is subsequently<br />

utilised. The sections that follow discuss these impacts with reference to the following<br />

possible uses <strong>of</strong> the gas:<br />

1. On-site combustion <strong>of</strong> biogas, generating electricity;<br />

2. Biogas upgrading and its subsequent use as a vehicle fuel displacing the use<br />

<strong>of</strong> diesel in a heavy goods vehicle such as a bus.<br />

63.9.1 Climate Change Impacts<br />

CO2 emissions resulting from the AD <strong>of</strong> source-separated organic waste are based on<br />

the carbon content <strong>of</strong> the input waste, assumed to 100% food waste for the purposes<br />

<strong>of</strong> this study. The carbon content is calculated on the basis <strong>of</strong> the total organic<br />

content <strong>of</strong> the waste and its volatile solids (VS) content. A proportion <strong>of</strong> the total<br />

carbon content will be converted to CO2 as a result <strong>of</strong> biogas combustion for energy<br />

generation. A further (albeit small) amount is emitted as CH4 through fugitive<br />

emissions occurring during the digestion process. Table 63-28 outlines key<br />

assumptions used to model the AD process within this study. 1271<br />

1271 For more information regarding the methodology used to model the AD process see Eunomia<br />

(2007) Managing Biowastes from Households in the UK: Applying Life-cycle Thinking in the Framework<br />

<strong>of</strong> Cost-benefit Analysis, Appendices to the Main Report, Report for WRAP, May 2007


Table 63-28: AD Process Emissions<br />

Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

Dry matter content <strong>of</strong> food waste 30%<br />

Organic matter content <strong>of</strong> VS 93%<br />

Carbon content <strong>of</strong> VS 45%<br />

VS content <strong>of</strong> organic matter 45%<br />

VS loss during digestion 70%<br />

Methane content <strong>of</strong> biogas 60%<br />

Electricity requirement 10% <strong>of</strong> biogas energy<br />

Heat requirement 125 kWh / t<br />

Fugitive emissions (% carbon converted to CH4) 1%<br />

Notes<br />

The energy requirement is assumed to be supplied by the plant itself (i.e. as parasitic load).<br />

No additional emissions are therefore associated with the use <strong>of</strong> this energy, but the biogas<br />

used in this way is assumed to be unavailable for further utilisation. The energy utilisation<br />

figures are based on data supplied by plant operating in the UK and Germany.<br />

Sources: Greenfinch (2005) Mass and Energy Balance: Ryegrass and Pig Slurry Biogas Plant,<br />

Produced for DTI, September 2005; University <strong>of</strong> Glamorgan, The Wales Centre <strong>of</strong> Excellence for<br />

Anaerobic Digestion and the Sustainable Environment Research Centre (2007) Ludlow (Greenfinch)<br />

Trial Scale Kitchen <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment Plant; H. Bachmaier, M Effenberger and A Gronauer (2008)<br />

Agricultural Biogas Production: What About the Climate Balance?, 17 th Annual Convention <strong>of</strong><br />

Fachverband Biogas e.V, 15 th -17 th January 2008, Nuremberg; Eunomia (2007) Managing Biowastes<br />

from Households in the UK: Applying Life-cycle Thinking in the Framework <strong>of</strong> Cost-benefit Analysis,<br />

Appendices to the Main Report, Report for WRAP, May 2007<br />

Assumptions used to model the on-site utilisation <strong>of</strong> biogas in a gas engine are<br />

presented in Table 63-29. These assumptions have been developed from data<br />

provided by German plant operators.<br />

Table 63-29: Emissions from the Use <strong>of</strong> Biogas in a Gas Engine<br />

Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

Gross electrical efficiency <strong>of</strong> gas engine 40%<br />

Fugitive emissions (gas engine slip) 2%<br />

Notes<br />

Net electrical efficiency is 30% taking into account parasitic load figures provided in Table<br />

63-28. The net electricity generation total is assumed to be 286 kWh per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste to<br />

the facility.<br />

Sources: H. Bachmaier, M Effenberger and A Gronauer (2008) Agricultural Biogas Production: What<br />

About the Climate Balance? 17 th Annual Convention <strong>of</strong> Fachverband Biogas e.V, 15 th -17 th January<br />

2008, Nuremberg; F. Scholwin (2008) The State <strong>of</strong> Treatment <strong>of</strong> Biogas for Feeding in the Natural Gas<br />

Network in Germany, 17 th Annual Convention <strong>of</strong> Fachverband Biogas e.V, 15 th -17 th January 2008,<br />

Nuremberg<br />

1026<br />

29/09/09


If the biogas is cleaned <strong>of</strong> impurities it can be subsequently used as a vehicle fuel,<br />

displacing the use <strong>of</strong> diesel. Our assumptions for modelling this option assume the<br />

fuel to be used within a fleet <strong>of</strong> vehicles, re-fuelled from a central point, as is the<br />

practice in Scandinavia and France. Some modification to the vehicle will be required<br />

to allow it to run on gas as opposed to diesel. Assumptions used to model this option<br />

are summarised in Table 63-30.<br />

Table 63-30: Emissions from the Use <strong>of</strong> Biogas in a Vehicle<br />

Parameter Parameter<br />

Assumption<br />

Assumption<br />

Energy used during upgrade process 0.2 kWh / Nm 3 biogas<br />

Process losses for CH4 (from upgrade process) 2%<br />

Fuel consumption <strong>of</strong> CBG bus 23.4 MJ / km<br />

Emissions avoided by diesel production 13.63 g CO2 equ / MJ<br />

Emissions from diesel bus 1,226 g CO2 equ / km<br />

Sources: W. Urban (2008) Methods and costs <strong>of</strong> the generation <strong>of</strong> natural gas substitutes from<br />

biomass – presentation <strong>of</strong> results <strong>of</strong> latest field research, 17 th Annual Convention <strong>of</strong> Fachverband<br />

Biogas e.V, 15 th -17 th January 2008, Nuremberg; N. Nylund, K. Erkkilä, M. Lappi, and M. Ikonen (2004)<br />

Transit Bus Emission Study: Comparison <strong>of</strong> Emissions from Diesel and Natural Gas Buses, VTT<br />

Processes, October 2004; Bio-NETT (2008) Bio-methane in Lille: A Case Study<br />

63.9.2 Air Quality Impacts<br />

63.9.2.1 Combustion <strong>of</strong> the Biogas in a Gas Engine<br />

Where biogas is used to generate energy using a gas engine, emissions are<br />

associated with the combustion process. The most significant air quality impacts<br />

resulting from the combustion <strong>of</strong> biogas relate to emissions <strong>of</strong> SOx and NOx.<br />

SOx emissions are generally a matter for process management. To the extent that<br />

they stem from the H2S in raw gas, the emissions are related to the use <strong>of</strong>, for<br />

example, precipitation salts which seek to precipitate out the sulphur emitted from<br />

the degradation <strong>of</strong> proteins as iron sulphide.<br />

NOx emissions result from high temperature reactions occurring between<br />

atmospheric nitrogen, and trace elements such as NH3 and H2S contained within the<br />

biogas. 1272 These emissions can be significantly reduced using Selective Catalytic<br />

Reduction (SCR) techniques. Use <strong>of</strong> this technique was cited as the Best Available<br />

Technique (BAT) in the Reference Document for the <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment Industries for<br />

MBT systems using AD. However, although this equipment is widely used to reduce<br />

NOx emissions from waste incineration facilities across Europe, use <strong>of</strong> SCR within AD<br />

1272 V. Aschmann, R Kissel and A Gronauer (2008) Efficiency and Environmental Compatibility <strong>of</strong><br />

Biogas Fired Cogeneration Plants in Practical Service, 17 th Annual Convention <strong>of</strong> Fachverband Biogas<br />

e.V, 15 th -17 th January 2008, Nuremberg<br />

1027<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


plant is still relatively limited. 1273 The air quality limits imposed upon AD facilities are<br />

typically less onerous than those for waste incinerators; thus there is a lack <strong>of</strong><br />

incentive to incur the further expense that the installation <strong>of</strong> this additional<br />

equipment requires.<br />

Table 63-31 outlines the emissions from the combustion <strong>of</strong> biogas using a gas<br />

engine. The table uses data from the previously cited Reference Document along with<br />

information supplied through emissions tests at an Australian MBT plant operated by<br />

Global Renewables Ltd (GRL). The latter may overstate emissions, being derived from<br />

mixed waste sources.<br />

Table 63-31: Emissions from the Combustion <strong>of</strong> Biogas<br />

1028<br />

29/09/09<br />

Emissions Emissions from from from biogas biogas combusti combustion combusti on (g / tonne<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> waste waste to to process)<br />

process)<br />

CO 200<br />

Dust 20<br />

NOx 250<br />

Hydrocarbons 40<br />

SO2 20<br />

Notes<br />

Emissions are calculated assuming 3,960 m 3 exhaust gas is produced per hour from each <strong>of</strong><br />

two gas engines, using data provided by GRL from their Eastern Creek MBT facility in Australia<br />

(that facility treats 70,000 tonnes <strong>of</strong> waste per year in the AD part <strong>of</strong> the plant).<br />

Sources: European Commission (2006) Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control: Reference<br />

Document on Best Available Techniques for the <strong>Waste</strong> Treatment Industries, August 2006; EML Air<br />

PTY (2008) Test Report Prepared for Eastern Creek Operations, report for Global Renewables Ltd, April<br />

2008; AEA (2007) Mechanical Biological Treatment: Case Study 2: Eastern Creek UR 3R Sydney,<br />

Report to IEA Bioenergy Task 36, April 2007<br />

However, as was previously indicated in Table 63-29 the plant is assumed to<br />

generate 286 kWh <strong>of</strong> electricity per tonne <strong>of</strong> waste to the facility, and emissions to air<br />

are assumed to be <strong>of</strong>fset as a result <strong>of</strong> this energy production. The avoided air<br />

emissions resulting from electricity generation are presented in Table 63-32,<br />

calculated using emissions data supplied by Ecoinvent for European CCGT plant. The<br />

data suggests that there is a marginal air quality benefit associated with generating<br />

electricity using AD in comparison to generation at larger scale CCGT plant. As gas<br />

turbine efficiencies increase, the resultant higher firing temperatures lead to greater<br />

NOx formation. Thus measures taken to reduce NOx formation will be less effective at<br />

the larger and more efficient CCGT plant. 1274 Levels <strong>of</strong> other emissions will depend on<br />

1273 It is understood, however, that authorities in The Netherlands wanted to impose this as standard<br />

for all AD facilities.<br />

1274 European Commission (2006) Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control: Reference Document<br />

on Best Available Techniques for Large Combustion Plants, July 2006


the source <strong>of</strong> the natural gas, and on the pollution control regime undertaken by the<br />

plant.<br />

Table 63-32: Emissions Offset by Electricity Generation at AD Plant<br />

1029<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Emissions Emissions Emissions from from biogas biogas combustion combustion combustion (g (g / / tonne tonne<br />

tonne<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> waste waste to to process)<br />

process)<br />

Dust -31<br />

NOx -268<br />

Hydrocarbons -15<br />

SO2 -35<br />

Source: Ecoinvent (2004) Ecoinvent Data v1.1, Final Reports Ecoinvent 2000, No. 1-15, Swiss Centre<br />

for Life Cycle Inventories, Dubendorf, 2004<br />

63.9.2.2 Use <strong>of</strong> the Upgraded Biogas to Fuel Vehicles<br />

The size <strong>of</strong> vehicle has a considerable impact on its emissions. Fuel consumption is<br />

far greater for heavier vehicles such as lorries and buses in comparison to cars,<br />

resulting in higher emissions per km. Both liquid fuel and gas operated heavy goods<br />

vehicles have seen considerable improvements in emissions over the past decade.<br />

There remains, however, considerable variation in performance between currently the<br />

available vehicles using either fuel.<br />

Table 63-33 shows the emissions data used within our model <strong>of</strong> environmental<br />

impacts associated with the use <strong>of</strong> biogas to fuel vehicles, taken from a Finnish study<br />

produced in 2003. This data has been used because compares gas operated and<br />

liquid fuelled engine performance using similar Euro III engines, thus allowing the<br />

differential in performance associated with the type <strong>of</strong> fuel to be more accurately<br />

assessed. Although the Finnish study looked at emissions from natural gas buses, as<br />

opposed to those fuelled on biogas, the data is consistent with emissions data from<br />

Scandinavia and France where biogas-fuelled buses are more widely used. 1275<br />

1275 C. Plombin (2003) Biogas as Vehicle Fuel: A European Overview: Trendsetter Report No 2003:3,<br />

Stockholm; Bio-NETT (2008) Bio-methane in Lille: A Case Study


Table 63-33: Emissions <strong>of</strong> Gas-fuelled and Diesel-fuelled Buses<br />

1030<br />

29/09/09<br />

Emissions Emissions g g / / km<br />

km<br />

NMHC NMHC<br />

NOx NOx<br />

PM PM<br />

Diesel 0.12 8.50 0.10<br />

Gas 0.03 4.60 0.01<br />

Source: N. Nylund, K. Erkkilä, M. Lappi, and M. Ikonen (2004) Transit Bus Emission Study: Comparison<br />

<strong>of</strong> Emissions from Diesel and Natural Gas Buses, VTT Processes, October 2004<br />

The data in Table 63-33 suggests the use <strong>of</strong> biogas to fuel vehicles should result in<br />

improvements to air quality, particularly with regard to the NOx emission.<br />

63.9.3 Compost Produced by AD Process<br />

The residues can either be dewatered, creating a solid and a liquid fraction, or used<br />

directly on land as a slurry, sometimes using flocculants in the process.<br />

Whilst there may be some arguments for direct spreading, not least that <strong>of</strong> cost, it is<br />

considered better practice to stabilise the solid residues (following dewatering<br />

depending upon the materials and the process) through an aerobic stage so as to<br />

produce a compost. One <strong>of</strong> the reasons for stabilising the solids from digestion is to<br />

reduce the potential for nitrogen to leach following application – the stabilisation<br />

process makes for an amendment with high organic matter content, but with reduced<br />

availability <strong>of</strong> nitrogen. The level <strong>of</strong> nutrients such as phosphorous is much lower than<br />

in, say, sludge based materials, making it possible to apply more organic material<br />

without creating problems <strong>of</strong> groundwater pollution / surface water run-<strong>of</strong>f.<br />

In this study, we have assumed that the digestion process is followed by an aerobic<br />

treatment phase, and that the early stages <strong>of</strong> the aerobic treatment employ a<br />

bi<strong>of</strong>ilter. This adds slightly to the costs <strong>of</strong> treatment, and some equipment suppliers<br />

prefer to make the slurry available without such a treatment step.<br />

Additional emissions <strong>of</strong> CO2 and NH3 are assumed to occur in the aerobic phase, and<br />

some additional CH4 is assumed to be emitted in the transition from the anaerobic to<br />

the aerobic phase. The use <strong>of</strong> the bi<strong>of</strong>ilter necessitates the use <strong>of</strong> some additional<br />

electricity.<br />

Emissions <strong>of</strong>fsets attributed to the use <strong>of</strong> the compost produced in this way are<br />

calculated using the same methodology described in Section 63.8.4.<br />

63.9.4 Summary – Damage Costs Associated with AD Processes<br />

Table 63-34 summarises the damage costs associated with treating source<br />

separated food waste in AD systems.


Table 63-34: Summary <strong>of</strong> Damage Costs – AD Systems<br />

1031<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Damage Damage costs, costs, € per tonne <strong>of</strong> input to process process<br />

On On-site On site use use <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> biogas biogas to<br />

to<br />

generate generate electricity<br />

electricity<br />

Use Use <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> upgraded upgraded biogas biogas to<br />

to<br />

fuel fuel fuel buses<br />

buses<br />

High High Low Low High High Low<br />

Low<br />

Climate Change €11.70 €9.75 €6.21 €5.20<br />

Air Quality - €0.25 - €0.09 - €5.21 - €1.81<br />

Benefits – use <strong>of</strong> compost - €7.32 - €6.83 - €7.32 - €6.83<br />

TOTALS €4.13 €2.83 - €6.32 - €3.44<br />

Notes<br />

Climate change and air quality impacts include the emissions <strong>of</strong>fsets attributable to the<br />

generation <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

63.10 Benefits <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Policy</strong> Package to Ireland<br />

We have attempted to calculate the benefits <strong>of</strong> the proposed policies in the Main<br />

Report to Ireland. The basis for the calculation is as follows:<br />

� The year for which benefits are calculated is 2016;<br />

� The benefits cover those from municipal waste only;<br />

� Growth rates are estimated as in Table 63-35;<br />

� Capture rates are assumed to be as in Table 63-36 (this level <strong>of</strong> capture will<br />

meet the targets set out);<br />

� A food waste prevention effect equivalent to 10% <strong>of</strong> food waste is assumed to<br />

be related to the introduction <strong>of</strong> food waste collections in households and<br />

commercial enterprises;<br />

� The greenhouse gas effects include all greenhouse gases, so do not reflect<br />

reporting to IPCC. The figures used are from previous sections in the Annex;<br />

� The monetised benefits from textiles recycling and food waste prevention<br />

relate to GHGs only;<br />

� For organics, we have assumed emissions <strong>of</strong> 0.25 tonnes CO2 equ per tonne<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste and we have assumed environmental costs (not benefits) <strong>of</strong> the<br />

average <strong>of</strong> the AD plant using electricity only, and the in-vessel composting<br />

plant modelled earlier in this Annex; and<br />

� The GHG benefits from avoided disposal are related only to biodegradable<br />

materials, and are calculated as an average <strong>of</strong> the non-landfill treatments<br />

modelled.<br />

The results for greenhouse gas savings are shown in Table 63-36. The overall<br />

environmental benefits are shown in Table 63-37. It can be seen that benefits in


excess <strong>of</strong> €76 million are expected, whilst the reduction in greenhouse gases is<br />

equivalent to more than 1.4 million tonnes <strong>of</strong> carbon dioxide.<br />

Table 63-35: Assumed Growth Rates from 2007<br />

2008 2008 2008 2009 2009 2010 2010 2010 2011 2011 2011 2012 2012 2012 2013 2013 2013 2014 2014 2014 2015 2015 2015 2016 2016<br />

2016<br />

Household -1% -3% -1% 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% 1%<br />

Non-household<br />

Municipal<br />

-3% -7% -2% 1% 2% 2% 2% 2% 2%<br />

Table 63-36: Capture Rates and GHG Benefits Relative to 2007 Performance<br />

Captures Captures<br />

Captures<br />

Additional Additional<br />

Additional<br />

Tonnage<br />

Tonnage<br />

Captured<br />

Captured<br />

GHG GHG<br />

GHG<br />

Benefits<br />

Benefits<br />

(tonnes (tonnes<br />

(tonnes<br />

CO CO2 CO equ) equ)<br />

equ)<br />

Paper 90% 292,240 181,189<br />

Glass 90% 29,982 8,995<br />

Plastic 40% 50,565 70,792<br />

Ferrous 85% 7,156 8,588<br />

Aluminium 85% 20,045 184,413<br />

Other Metals 85% 3,034 15,779<br />

Textiles 60% 136,591 413,872<br />

Organics 75% 574,211 -143,553<br />

Wood 50% / 99% 3,451 3<br />

Food <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention (@10%) 206,053<br />

Avoided Disposal 469,099<br />

TOTAL 1,415,230<br />

Note: A positive figure denotes a a reduction in GHGs<br />

Table 63-37: Environmental Benefits Relative to 2007 Performance<br />

Activity<br />

Activity<br />

Environmental<br />

Environmental<br />

Benefit Benefit ( (€) (<br />

€)<br />

Separate Collection €45,741,864.247<br />

Avoided Disposal €24,878,888.57<br />

Food <strong>Waste</strong> Prevention (@10%, GHG benefit only) €5,975,547.29<br />

TOTAL €76,596,300.10<br />

Note: A positive figure denotes a benefit (a reduction in environmental costs)<br />

1032<br />

29/09/09


64.0 Costs <strong>of</strong> Household <strong>Waste</strong> Collection<br />

64.1 Background – The <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Market Operating in<br />

Ireland<br />

The chargeable waste collection services operated in Ireland are practically unique.<br />

The collection market is effectively an open one in which private companies and local<br />

authorities alike are competing against one another. The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> Act<br />

(1996) stipulates that all local authorities in Ireland are obliged to collect or arrange<br />

for the collection <strong>of</strong> domestic waste in their area. However, as discussed in the policy<br />

review annex, though this means that local authorities are responsible for<br />

administering the permits to collect waste, there is no control on individual<br />

households as to how they choose to avail themselves (or not) <strong>of</strong> the services <strong>of</strong>fered,<br />

and only limited control (though the collection permits) on how the waste is<br />

subsequently managed. 1276<br />

A consequence <strong>of</strong> the free market for waste collection is that collection routing<br />

(referred to as round design) probably suffers inefficiencies due to low customer<br />

densities. In addition, spatial logistics may be less than optimal with regard to cost in<br />

that average distances (and hence, other things being equal, journey times) from<br />

depots to rounds might be expected to be longer where different collection operators<br />

are operating in overlapping territories.<br />

Organised competition for providing collection services is certainly to be encouraged<br />

as it forces contractors to optimise for cost efficient services. In the majority <strong>of</strong><br />

instances around Europe (and worldwide), however, the competition is conducted<br />

through a tendering process to win a contract for comprehensive collection from all<br />

households. In some cases, local authorities themselves provide the service.<br />

However, the situation where the competition remains open on a day by day basis<br />

leads to multiple companies being operational in an area, even though they may only<br />

have a small number <strong>of</strong> customers in any one street. Collection costs per household<br />

naturally suffer due to the impact that this has on the efficiency <strong>of</strong> utilisation <strong>of</strong> staff<br />

and vehicles.<br />

Using an analogy to the electricity supply market, rather than customers all using the<br />

one set <strong>of</strong> power lines, it is much like a number <strong>of</strong> different companies all providing<br />

their own power lines in every street, with households selecting their cable <strong>of</strong> choice.<br />

The total costs <strong>of</strong> providing the service are greatly increased, and the efficiency in the<br />

way in which the service is provided is reduced. In situations where such services are<br />

provided in a genuinely competitive market, ironically, the costs may rise to users<br />

even as the margins to operators decline. In short, nobody wins.<br />

1276 The collection permit system does appear to be being deployed with increased vigour by the<br />

relevant authorities so that this level <strong>of</strong> control may be increasing.<br />

1033<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


This annex attempts to interrogate the costs borne by households for their waste<br />

services in Ireland, and to deconstruct them to assess the fundamental issues that<br />

may be obstructing value for money.<br />

64.2 Collection Service Case Studies in Irish County Councils<br />

There has recently been a move towards the roll out <strong>of</strong> organics collection in many<br />

parts <strong>of</strong> Ireland in recognition (by county councils and Joint <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

Plans) <strong>of</strong> the desirability <strong>of</strong> diverting biodegradable waste from landfill. In 2007, the<br />

EPA reported that 14 <strong>of</strong> the local authorities had some brown bin collections in their<br />

area, but in only 5 <strong>of</strong> these were more than 1,000 tonnes being collected (see Table<br />

64-1). Only in Galway City was the private sector achieving such rates. It can<br />

reasonably be suggested therefore that the majority <strong>of</strong> the households are still not<br />

served with a brown bin collection.<br />

Table 64-1: Separate Collection <strong>of</strong> Household Organic <strong>Waste</strong><br />

Local Local Authority Authority<br />

2006 2006<br />

2007<br />

2007<br />

Separate Separate Separate Kerbside Kerbside Collection Collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Food<br />

Food Separate Separate Separate Kerbside Kerbside Kerbside Collection Collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Food<br />

Food<br />

and and Garden Garden waste waste (brown (brown bins)<br />

bins) and and Garden Garden waste waste (brown (brown bins)<br />

(tonnes)<br />

(tonnes)<br />

(tonnes) (tonnes)<br />

(tonnes)<br />

Local Local Authority Authority Authority Private Private Operator Operator Local Local Authority Authority Authority Private Private Operator<br />

Operator<br />

Dublin City<br />

Council<br />

411 1,315<br />

Dun Laoghaire-<br />

Rathdown<br />

285<br />

Fingal County<br />

Council<br />

1,971 3,266<br />

Galway City<br />

Council<br />

4,987 774 4,163 1,968<br />

Galway County<br />

Council<br />

883 889<br />

Kerry County<br />

Council<br />

345 368<br />

Louth County<br />

Council<br />

346<br />

Mayo County<br />

Council<br />

127<br />

Monaghan County<br />

Council<br />

27<br />

South Dublin<br />

County Council<br />

36<br />

Waterford City<br />

Council<br />

3,766 3,976<br />

Waterford County<br />

Council<br />

2,165 2,123<br />

Westmeath<br />

County Council<br />

10 90<br />

Wicklow County<br />

Council<br />

10<br />

Total Total<br />

13,655 13,655 13,655<br />

1,942 1,942<br />

15,312 15,312<br />

3,393<br />

3,393<br />

Source: EPA (2009) National <strong>Waste</strong> Report 2007, Johnstown Castle Estate, Wexford: EPA.<br />

1034<br />

29/09/09


Within the following section we assess the waste collection systems that have been<br />

operating over the past few years against the available data on waste tonnages<br />

collected and collection costs.<br />

The most common collection systems that have been operating in Ireland over the<br />

past few years are twin bin, alternating fortnightly collections <strong>of</strong> residual waste and<br />

recyclable materials. The basis for the annual levies for waste collection faced by<br />

individual households is <strong>of</strong>ten not clear, in many cases not even to the households<br />

themselves. As such, we attempt here to draw together information on the typical<br />

fees paid by households in a number <strong>of</strong> areas around the country.<br />

Anecdotal evidence from an OLAM Briefing presentation for the CCMA Environment<br />

Committee suggests that the green bin recycling services cost the four Dublin local<br />

authorities €27 million per annum in 2006. 1277 This includes the costs associated<br />

with collecting, transporting, segregating, processing, shipping and marketing etc. It<br />

goes on to state that Repak contributes €1 million, while the sale <strong>of</strong> the processed<br />

product collected from households generates approximately €500,000. A significant<br />

cost, therefore, is attributable just to providing the collection services.<br />

Dividing the annual €27 million by the total <strong>of</strong> 380,000 households in these<br />

authorities suggests providing the services costs €70 per household per year for a<br />

fortnightly wheeled bin recycling collection service. This assumes that all households<br />

use the local authority service, which they might not due to a) their opting out (dealing<br />

with waste themselves) or b) their using the services <strong>of</strong> a private sector company. If<br />

the number is smaller, the average cost is higher. Total captures <strong>of</strong> recyclables at the<br />

kerbside under this system stand at around 180kg/hh/yr. It is important to note that<br />

where household waste services are concerned, ‘cost per household’ are a somewhat<br />

better measure than ‘cost per tonne’ (though both provide relevant information). This<br />

is because:<br />

1035<br />

� The costs <strong>of</strong> different elements <strong>of</strong> a service can contribute to reductions<br />

elsewhere;<br />

� Different systems may draw more or less material into the waste stream (and<br />

those that draw more in will have lower costs per tonne than those that do<br />

not); and finally,<br />

� What matters most from the household perspective is what they need to pay.<br />

The following review seeks to bring together more evidence on collection services and<br />

their associated costs in a snapshot <strong>of</strong> instances across the country. The<br />

government’s circular 06/06 sought to assemble detail on the collection services<br />

operated in individual counties together with fee structures and the charges levied.<br />

Extracts from this data, supplemented by information gained from council and<br />

1277 Murphy, R (2006) Managing The Environment: A Key Financial Challenge For Local Authorities,<br />

OLAM Briefing for CCMA Environment Committee, February 2006.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


collection operator websites and other sources 1278, are summarised for some<br />

example flat rate fee services in Table 64-2.<br />

Table 64-2: Sample <strong>of</strong> Flat Rate Standing Charge <strong>Waste</strong> Collection Levies in Irish<br />

Counties<br />

County County, County County , Service<br />

Collection<br />

Collection Details Details<br />

Charges Charges Levied<br />

Levied<br />

Provider<br />

Provider service service<br />

service<br />

Westmeath –<br />

Mahons<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly<br />

None<br />

Standing charge €348 for 240l residual<br />

bin, €288 for 140l (recycling free)<br />

Wexford<br />

County/Borough<br />

Council<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly<br />

None<br />

Various rates from €260 (80l bin) to<br />

€516 (240l)<br />

Cork - Country<br />

Clean<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly<br />

None<br />

€300 pa for 240l residual bin, recycling<br />

free<br />

Galway – City<br />

Bin<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly<br />

€259 fixed fee<br />

Kilkenny –<br />

Greenstar<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly<br />

None<br />

€369 pa for 240l residual bin, €299 for<br />

140l residual bin; both with 240l<br />

recyclates bin<br />

Residual Weekly<br />

Fingal – Panda Recycling Fortnightly<br />

€282 pa, fixed fee<br />

Louth<br />

Organics Fortnightly<br />

(Drogheda) –<br />

Panda<br />

Residual Weekly €282 pa, fixed fee<br />

Residual Every 3 weeks<br />

Waterford Recycling Every 3 weeks<br />

€320 pa, fixed fee<br />

Organics Every 3 weeks<br />

Where charges are levied according to the frequency or weight <strong>of</strong> material set out for<br />

collection, annual charges to households will be variable. Charging structures for an<br />

example set <strong>of</strong> pay by use (PBU) or pay by weight (PBW) services are given in Table<br />

64-3.<br />

The total annual fees payable by households in such cases where there is a variable<br />

element to the charge are less transparent. It is however, possible to estimate some<br />

typical costs in these circumstances by bringing together waste generation data from<br />

the national waste reports and (where charges are levied for each pickup) making<br />

assumptions on the number <strong>of</strong> collections required per annum. In general, at the<br />

levels <strong>of</strong> residual waste generation observable in Ireland, it is likely for a typical<br />

household to require a 240l wheeled bin to be emptied once per fortnight, although<br />

this might fall to once a month, perhaps less frequently for some households (the<br />

frequency required would be expected to fall with well designed biowaste collections<br />

1278 Sunday Business Post (14 June 2009), <strong>Waste</strong> Not, Want Not, www.thepost.ie/story/eycweykfau<br />

1036<br />

29/09/09


in place). It is possible to sense-check this against the collected waste tonnage data<br />

by using approximate bulk densities for waste and recycling. 1279 However, this<br />

requires knowledge <strong>of</strong> how many households are using collection services. The fact<br />

that there is no obligation on households to subscribe to a collection service is an<br />

important one. Statistics on the number <strong>of</strong> households subscribing to collection<br />

systems are hard to come by. The simplistic approach we use to quantify participation<br />

here is to consider the tonnage <strong>of</strong> waste collected through kerbside operations and<br />

relative to waste managed by other means (bring sites, civic amenity, direct to landfill,<br />

home composting estimates and ‘uncollected waste’). This allows approximate typical<br />

weights and volumes <strong>of</strong> waste produced per participating household to be estimated,<br />

and for resulting annual charge levels to be quantified. 1280 Such an analysis is<br />

undertaken in Table 64-4.<br />

Table 64-3: Sample <strong>of</strong> Variable Charging Collection Systems<br />

County County, County Collection<br />

Collection Details Details Details<br />

Charges Charges Levied<br />

Levied<br />

Service<br />

Service<br />

Provider<br />

Provider<br />

service<br />

service<br />

Dublin City<br />

Council /<br />

Greyhound<br />

PBU<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly bin (paper,<br />

card, cans, plastics)<br />

Fortnightly<br />

€84 + €5.25 / lift for 240l bin. Other<br />

charges for sacks / different sized bins.<br />

-<br />

€2 / lift for wheeled bin<br />

South<br />

Tipperary CC<br />

PBU<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly bin (paper,<br />

card, cans, plastics)<br />

None<br />

€210 + €7 / lift for 240l bin<br />

€0.70 / recyclable bag<br />

-<br />

Westmeath -<br />

Mulleadys<br />

PBW<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly (paper, card,<br />

tetrapak, cans, plastics)<br />

None<br />

€208 + €0.17/kg<br />

-<br />

-<br />

Westmeath -<br />

Mulleadys<br />

PBU<br />

Residual<br />

Recycling<br />

Organics<br />

Fortnightly<br />

Fortnightly (paper, card,<br />

tetrapak, cans, plastics)<br />

None<br />

€7.50 / lift<br />

€4.00 / lift<br />

-<br />

Westmeath - Residual Fortnightly €8.00 / lift (240l bin)<br />

Wallace Recycling Fortnightly €3.00 / lift<br />

PBU Organics None -<br />

Cork County Residual Fortnightly €120 + €0.46 / kg<br />

Council Recycling Fortnightly -<br />

PBW Organics None -<br />

Cork County - Residual Weekly €418 + €0.162/kg over 400kg/annum<br />

Mr Binman Recycling Weekly -<br />

PBW Organics None -<br />

1279 We may assume for the sake <strong>of</strong> this analysis a residual waste bulk density <strong>of</strong> 200kg/m 3 , mixed<br />

recycling excluding glass <strong>of</strong> 150kg/m 3 and (though <strong>of</strong> less relevance here) mixed organic waste <strong>of</strong><br />

400kg/m 3 .<br />

1280 This clearly does not allow for any link between the nature <strong>of</strong> the charging system and the quantity<br />

<strong>of</strong> waste set out. As such, it is an approximation to the actual costs likely to face households.<br />

1037<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


The data in the tables above when combined with Table 64-4, shows households<br />

being charged an estimated €220 to €420 per household per annum for alternating<br />

fortnightly collection services. The example weekly waste and recycling collection<br />

services are up to €464 per household per annum. Obviously this cost has to cover<br />

both the collection costs, as well as the processing / recycling / disposal <strong>of</strong> the<br />

material. We may assume to isolate the collection service provision costs (vehicles,<br />

staff, containers) by simply subtracting the calculated costs <strong>of</strong> treating / disposing <strong>of</strong><br />

the collected material. This calculation is performed in Table 64-5 using a cost for<br />

residual waste disposal <strong>of</strong> €120/tonne, a cost for sorting mixed recyclables<br />

(excluding glass) <strong>of</strong> €40/tonne, and (where relevant) for composting mixed biowaste<br />

<strong>of</strong> €80/tonne. In the case <strong>of</strong> private sector contractors VAT is payable on disposal<br />

costs. As such, in these instances we account 13.5% VAT on private sector disposal<br />

costs in Table 64-5, but deduct the VAT for the final column.<br />

The evaluated costs in Table 64-5 are particularly revealing. Calculated by deducting<br />

the organic treatment and residual disposal costs (in Table 64-5) from the charges<br />

levied (in Table 64-4), they show a range <strong>of</strong> costs for collection only (excluding VAT) <strong>of</strong><br />

between €113 and €316 per household per annum for an alternating weekly<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> waste and recyclables, and the one example weekly service over €380<br />

per household per annum.<br />

Such figures are greatly in excess <strong>of</strong> costs borne by collection services in other<br />

countries. The following section provides some international perspective on waste<br />

management costs.<br />

1038<br />

29/09/09


Table 64-4: Household Annual Collection Cost Estimates<br />

County County, County , Serv Service Serv<br />

ice ice Provider;<br />

Collection Collection<br />

Collection Annual Annual<br />

Annual Estima<br />

Estima kg/<br />

litres/<br />

litres/ Estimated Estimated<br />

Estimated Calculated Calculated<br />

Calculated Total Total<br />

Total<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> households in county; service<br />

service kerbside<br />

kerbside ted<br />

ted particip<br />

particip wk wk<br />

collection collection<br />

collection charge charge per<br />

per charge<br />

charge<br />

Proportion <strong>of</strong> total county waste<br />

tonnage<br />

tonnage partici<br />

partici ating ating-<br />

ating<br />

requirement<br />

requirement participating<br />

participating /<br />

collected through kerbside services<br />

pation pation<br />

pation hhld/yr<br />

hhld/yr<br />

(rel (relevant (rel (relevant<br />

evant in the<br />

household<br />

household house house-<br />

house<br />

case case <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> PBU<br />

PBU<br />

hold hold /<br />

/<br />

charging)<br />

charging)<br />

annum annum<br />

annum<br />

Dublin Dublin City City Council Council / / / Greyhound Greyhound PBU PBU Residual 145,070 88% 912 88 Fortnightly €221<br />

Households: 180,852 Recycling 25,704 88% 162 21 n/a €0<br />

Kerbside as % <strong>of</strong> total waste: 88% Organics 1,315 3% 242 12 Monthly €24 €245<br />

South South South Tipp Tipp County County Council Council PBU Residual 16,787 74% 862 83 Fortnightly €392<br />

Households: 26,410 Recycling 6,626 74% 340 44<br />

3 in 4 weeks<br />

(for 60l sacks)<br />

€27<br />

Kerbside as % <strong>of</strong> total waste: 74% Organics 0 0% 0 0 - €0 €419<br />

Westmeath Westmeath - Mulleadys PBW Residual 14,493 71% 874 84 n/a €357<br />

Households: 23,360 Recycling 4,161 71% 251 32 n/a €0<br />

Kerbside as % <strong>of</strong> total waste: 71% Organics 90 0% 0 0 - €0 €357<br />

Westmeath Westmeath - Mulleadys PBU Residual 14,493 71% 874 84 Fortnightly €195<br />

Households: 23,360 Recycling 4,161 71% 251 32<br />

4 weekly (for<br />

240l bin)<br />

€52<br />

Kerbside as % <strong>of</strong> total waste: 71% Organics 90 0% 0 0 - €0 €247<br />

Westmeath Westmeath - Wallace PBU Residual 14,493 71% 874 84 Fortnightly €208<br />

Households: 23,360 Recycling 4,161 71% 251 32<br />

4 weekly (for<br />

240l bin)<br />

€39<br />

Kerbside as % <strong>of</strong> total waste: 71% Organics 90 0% 0 0 - €0 €247<br />

Cork Cork County County Council Council PBW Residual 48,391 67% 686 66 n/a €436<br />

Households: 105,248 Recycling 22,370 67% 317 41 n/a €0<br />

Kerbside as % <strong>of</strong> total waste: 67% Organics 0 0% 0 0 - €0 €218<br />

Cork Cork County County - Mr Binman PBW PBW Residual 48,391 67% 686 66 n/a €464<br />

Households: 105,248 Recycling 22,370 67% 317 41 n/a €0<br />

Kerbside as % <strong>of</strong> total waste: 67% Organics 0 0% 0 0 - €0 €464<br />

Note: As opposed to council operated services, private sector contractor costs are liable to (and are shown to include) VAT payable at 13.5%.<br />

1039<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


Table 64-5: Breakdown <strong>of</strong> Costs into Individual Collection Systems<br />

County County, County County , Service<br />

Provider<br />

Provider<br />

1040<br />

29/09/09<br />

Collection Collection service service service kg/<br />

participating-<br />

participating<br />

hhld/yr<br />

hhld/yr<br />

Calculated Calculated<br />

Calculated<br />

residual<br />

residual<br />

disposal disposal, disposal , MRF<br />

sorting sorting and<br />

and<br />

organic<br />

organic<br />

treatment reatment<br />

costs costs / hhld<br />

Dublin City Fortnightly residual 912 €109<br />

Council / Fortnightly recycling 162 €6<br />

Greyhound PBU Fortnightly organics 242 €19<br />

South Tipp CC Fortnightly residual 862 €103<br />

PBU Fortnightly recycling 340 €14<br />

Westmeath – Fortnightly residual 874 €119<br />

Mulleadys PBW Fortnightly recycling 251 €10<br />

Westmeath – Fortnightly residual 874 €119<br />

Mulleadys PBU Fortnightly recycling 251 €10<br />

Westmeath – Fortnightly residual 874 €119<br />

Wallace PBU Fortnightly recycling 251 €10<br />

Cork County Fortnightly residual 686 €82<br />

Council PBW Fortnightly recycling 317 €13<br />

Cork County - Weekly residual 686 €82<br />

Mr Binman PBW Weekly recycling 317 €13<br />

Total Total<br />

Total<br />

organic<br />

organic<br />

treatment treatment &<br />

&<br />

residual residual<br />

residual<br />

disposal<br />

disposal<br />

costs costs / hhld<br />

(excluding (excluding<br />

(excluding<br />

MRF MRF fees)<br />

fees)<br />

Remaining<br />

Remaining<br />

cost cost cost to to cover<br />

cover<br />

collec collection collec collection<br />

tion<br />

expenditure<br />

expenditure<br />

/ / hhld<br />

hhld<br />

(excl (excl VAT)<br />

VAT)<br />

(including<br />

(including<br />

MRF MRF fees fees )<br />

)<br />

€129 €116<br />

€103 €316<br />

€119 €209<br />

€119 €113<br />

€119 €113<br />

€82 €135<br />

€82 €382<br />

Note: Blue figures indicate private sector service providers where VAT (payable at 13.5%) is levied on<br />

waste disposal costs. For consistency, the VAT has been deducted from these private sector costs for<br />

the final column to be comparative with international collection costs as investigated below.<br />

64.3 Comparisons to <strong>International</strong> Collection Costs<br />

64.3.1 Collection in Wales: Hitting 70% Recycling<br />

The most thorough publicly available report from WRAP on expected costs <strong>of</strong> kerbside<br />

collections is a recent study for Wales. 1281 For this report, modelling was undertaken<br />

<strong>of</strong> services designed to deliver up to the country targets <strong>of</strong> 70% recycling/composting.<br />

Data from this study is compiled in Table 64-6 (some interpretation <strong>of</strong> the data was<br />

necessary to generate collection costs per household including recycling<br />

income/sorting fees, the figures are calculated based on the data presented in the<br />

report). Here, the collection only costs per tonne from Figure 10 in the WRAP report<br />

(using a relatively generous £1 to €1.33 exchange rate) together with yields and gate<br />

fee data suggests that a commingled fortnightly bin recycling service alongside a<br />

fortnightly refuse collection ought to be deliverable at a maximum collection cost <strong>of</strong><br />

€73 per household per annum. The systems modelled here are somewhat more<br />

comprehensive to the Ireland alternating fortnightly collections and yet they again are<br />

much lower than the Ireland costs evaluated for Table 64-5.<br />

1281 Priestley-Leach, O,, Bragg, J (2009) Kerbside recycling in Wales: Indicative Financial Costs, WRAP,<br />

March 2009


Table 64-6: Interpretation <strong>of</strong> WRAP Report Data and Calculations to Determine Comparative Collection Costs<br />

WRAP WRAP modelled<br />

modelled<br />

data data data for for Wales Wales<br />

Wales<br />

System description<br />

Collection only cost<br />

per tonne (£)<br />

Collection only cost<br />

per tonne (€)<br />

Yield: kerbside<br />

recyclables + food<br />

waste (kg/hhld/yr)<br />

Yield: kerbside<br />

recyclables only<br />

(kg/hhld/yr)<br />

Total kerbside<br />

collected waste<br />

(kg/hhld/yr)<br />

Total collection cost<br />

per household<br />

(all services)<br />

excluding recycling<br />

fees / revenues<br />

Total collection cost<br />

per household<br />

(all services)<br />

including recycling<br />

fees / revenues<br />

1041<br />

Single Single stream<br />

stream<br />

fortnightly fortnightly recycling<br />

recycling<br />

Fortnightly<br />

recycling RCV +<br />

food waste pod.<br />

Fortnightly residual<br />

RCV + food pod.<br />

210<br />

(MRF fees =<br />

£33/tonne)<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

Single Single stream<br />

stream<br />

weekly weekly recycling<br />

recycling<br />

Weekly recycling +<br />

food waste pod.<br />

Weekly residual<br />

RCV.<br />

Kerbside Kerbside sort<br />

sort<br />

stillage stillage vehicle<br />

vehicle<br />

Weekly stillage<br />

vehicle (including<br />

food). Fortnightly<br />

residual RVC.<br />

Kerbside Kerbside Kerbside sort<br />

sort<br />

Labrie Labrie vehicle vehicle<br />

vehicle<br />

Weekly recycling<br />

vehicle with<br />

compaction for<br />

cans/plastic.<br />

Fortnightly residual<br />

RVC.<br />

Two Two stream stream weekly weekly<br />

weekly<br />

recycling<br />

recycling<br />

Weekly recycling<br />

/food spit RCV.<br />

Fortnightly residual<br />

RCV.<br />

Two Two stream<br />

stream<br />

fortnightly fortnightly fortnightly recycling<br />

recycling<br />

Fortnightly<br />

recycling /food spit<br />

RCV. Fortnightly<br />

food mini-RCV.<br />

Fortnightly residual<br />

RCV.<br />

£58 £52 £59 £57 £57 £50<br />

€77 €69 €78 €76 €76 €67<br />

372 372 377 377 384 384<br />

210<br />

(MRF fees =<br />

£33/tonne)<br />

181<br />

(income calculated<br />

from figures in<br />

report to average<br />

£62/tonne)<br />

181<br />

(income calculated<br />

from figures in<br />

report to average<br />

£62/tonne)<br />

210<br />

(zero cost for<br />

containers, £7/t<br />

income for fibres)<br />

210<br />

(zero cost for<br />

containers, £7/t<br />

income for fibres)<br />

926 926 926 926 926 926<br />

€71 €64 €73 €70 €70 €62<br />

€81 €73 €58 €55 €70 €62


The kerbside sort systems shown in the Table, which suggest a lower cost, are not so<br />

relevant in the current context as few if any are currently operated in Ireland.<br />

Nevertheless, they are <strong>of</strong> relevance more generally. <strong>International</strong> experience, indeed,<br />

including from Northern Ireland, shows that kerbside sort approaches can be<br />

particularly cost competitive on collection costs alone. The particular advantage they<br />

hold is that since material is segregated at collection, it can be sold direct to recovery<br />

markets rather than incurring sorting costs. Issues <strong>of</strong> contamination and rejects are<br />

also largely avoided.<br />

64.3.2 Collection in Eden District Council, England<br />

The collection services operated in Eden District Council are interesting to compare to<br />

the situation in Ireland. Throughout the review we have undertaken, it has been<br />

argued that Ireland is in some way ‘unique’, and that as a result, the collection<br />

systems in place in other countries might not be transferable to the Irish context. One<br />

<strong>of</strong> the arguments advanced in support <strong>of</strong> Ireland’s ‘uniqueness’ is its low population<br />

density. Clearly, though, the majority <strong>of</strong> countries have both urban and rural areas,<br />

and few are uniquely composed <strong>of</strong> one or the other.<br />

Eden is the least densely populated local authority in England, with a population <strong>of</strong> 23<br />

persons per square kilometre. The average population density across the Republic <strong>of</strong><br />

Ireland as a whole stands at 60/km 2 , with a range from Dublin City at 4,304/km 2 , to<br />

Leitrim at 18/km 2 and Mayo 22/km 2 . As such it may be fair to parallel Eden with the<br />

more remote areas <strong>of</strong> Ireland. 1282<br />

The services operated in Eden are a weekly sack based collection <strong>of</strong> refuse from all<br />

24,000 households, fortnightly kerbside sort collection <strong>of</strong> dry recyclable materials<br />

(paper, cans and glass) from 15,000 households, and a fortnightly (4-weekly in<br />

winter) collection <strong>of</strong> garden waste from 15,000 households using wheeled bins.<br />

Data from Eden’s revised waste management strategy gives detail on the costs paid<br />

to collection contractors for the separate collection systems in operation. The figure <strong>of</strong><br />

£158,000 is quoted for a fortnightly kerbside sort collection operation provided to<br />

15,839 households in the district. Using an exchange rate <strong>of</strong> £1.33 to €1, this<br />

equates to a collection service cost <strong>of</strong> €13 per household per annum.<br />

We have specific insight into the collection systems operated in Eden having<br />

conducted detailed cost modelling in a WRAP-funded study, for the authority, <strong>of</strong> the<br />

existing and potential replacement collection systems in the district. Our proprietary<br />

collection cost model, Hermes, has to date been used to model collection systems for<br />

around 25% <strong>of</strong> local authorities in the UK, frequently in the context <strong>of</strong> local authority<br />

business cases and procurements, and sometimes used with contractors<br />

interrogating the model, giving us some confidence in the costs and performance <strong>of</strong> a<br />

vast range <strong>of</strong> different collection systems operated in different environments.<br />

The baseline service in Eden includes:<br />

1282 http://www.cso.ie/newsevents/pr_census2006vol1.htm<br />

1042<br />

29/09/09


1043<br />

� Refuse collected weekly in sacks (all households);<br />

� Free garden waste collection is provided to some (not all) households; and<br />

� Dry recyclables are collected from some (not all) households.<br />

The total collection cost for all kerbside collection services in Eden was evaluated to<br />

be €67 per household per annum.<br />

In assessing the potential cost <strong>of</strong> alternative services five options were assessed (in<br />

each case all services were <strong>of</strong>fered to all households).<br />

Option Option 1 1 1 – Weekly Weekly collection collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> food food waste waste using using a a a sep separate sep arate pass single single operative<br />

operative<br />

vehicle. vehicle.<br />

vehicle.<br />

Option Option Option 1 1 1 Sensitivity Sensitivity Sensitivity Analysis Analysis<br />

Analysis<br />

Option Option 2 2 – Fortnightly Fortnightly co co-mingled co mingled collection collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> food food and and garden garden waste waste using using RCVs RCVs 1283<br />

Option Option Option 3 3 3 – Co Co-collection Co collection collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> food food waste waste with with dry recyclables recyclables one one week week week and and and a a separate separate<br />

separate<br />

pass pass pass single single single operative operative operative vehicle vehicle on on the the alternate alternate week. week. week. Card Card Card to to to be be be added added added to to the the<br />

fortnightly fortnightly fortnightly garden garden garden waste waste waste collection. collection.<br />

collection.<br />

Option Option Option 4 4 4 – Co Co-collection Co collection collection <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> residual residual residual and and and food food food waste waste waste in in in split split split bodied bodied bodied vehicles. vehicles.<br />

vehicles.<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> the modelling are shown below relative to an ‘Intermediate Baseline’<br />

where the dry recyclables services modelled in the Options are made the same as<br />

those where biowaste collections are added.<br />

It can be seen that the total system costs can show a drop, particularly under the ‘B’<br />

scenarios. In the A scenarios, the refuse collection remains on a weekly basis (in<br />

sacks) whilst in the B scenarios, refuse is collected fortnightly in bins. This saving –<br />

associated with reduced costs <strong>of</strong> collection – along with the avoided costs <strong>of</strong><br />

disposal, more than <strong>of</strong>fset the increase in cost for providing the additional biowaste<br />

collection and the treatment <strong>of</strong> biowaste.<br />

1283 RCVs would need to be suitable for the collection <strong>of</strong> mixed food and garden wastes – the<br />

additional liquid in the food waste may require minor modifications to be specified.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes<br />

1283.


Table 64-7: Additional Cost per Household (relative to Intermediate Baseline)<br />

-£10<br />

1044<br />

£20<br />

£15<br />

£10<br />

£5<br />

£-<br />

-£5<br />

29/09/09<br />

Option<br />

1A<br />

Option<br />

1B<br />

Option<br />

2A<br />

Option<br />

2B<br />

Option<br />

3A<br />

Option<br />

3B<br />

Option<br />

3C<br />

Option<br />

4A<br />

Option<br />

4B<br />

Option<br />

1A/k<br />

Option<br />

1A/c<br />

Source: Eunomia (2007) Cost & Performance Modelling <strong>of</strong> Kerbside Collection Options, Report to Eden<br />

District Council supported by WRAP.<br />

64.3.3 Collection in Ballymoney & Coleraine Borough Councils, Northern<br />

Ireland<br />

We have also carried out collection modelling for two borough councils in Northern<br />

Ireland which have particular relevance when comparing to the Republic <strong>of</strong> Ireland<br />

(ROI). In these cases, both authorities were operating an alternating fortnightly<br />

collection <strong>of</strong> waste and recyclables (paper, card, plastic bottles and cans) – the same<br />

as the typical ROI system. Full details on the services were provided to allow us to<br />

model the existing systems and compare against alternate collection options in order<br />

to advise on collection strategies.<br />

For purposes here we extract the relevant data on the existing services direct from<br />

the modelling and convert to Euros. The results which are comparable to the figures<br />

for the ROI in the rest <strong>of</strong> the report are shown in Table 64-8.<br />

Table 64-8: Data Extracted from Collection Modelling for Northern Ireland Authorities<br />

Ballymoney Ballymoney Ballymoney<br />

Coleraine Coleraine<br />

Coleraine<br />

Average vehicle crewing level Driver plus 1 Driver plus 2<br />

Households served / vehicle / day 706 890<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> unloads / vehicle / day<br />

1 (recycling)<br />

2 (residual)<br />

1 (recycling)<br />

2 (residual)<br />

Calculated total collection cost per household<br />

per annum (staff, vehicles, fuel, etc.)<br />

€54 €55<br />

Recycling, kg/household/year 119 108<br />

Residual waste collected, kg/household/year 599 611


The nature <strong>of</strong> these authorities themselves is also worth some consideration.<br />

Ballymoney Borough Council is a predominantly rural authority with 27,000 residents<br />

and a population density <strong>of</strong> 70 people per square kilometre. Approximately one third<br />

<strong>of</strong> the population live in Ballymoney town. Coleraine Borough Council, an important<br />

tourist destination has a somewhat seasonal population <strong>of</strong> around 56,000, a<br />

population density <strong>of</strong> 115 people per square kilometre and over 40% <strong>of</strong> residents<br />

living within the town <strong>of</strong> Coleraine. Although these districts may be fairly<br />

representative <strong>of</strong> the general topography <strong>of</strong> the ROI, they have untypically small<br />

administrative boundary areas.<br />

The issue this presents, particularly in the Ballymoney case, is that only a very small<br />

number <strong>of</strong> collection vehicles are required. As such, they tend to be less efficiently<br />

utilised. Ballymoney, using just two vehicles for recycling and two for residual waste,<br />

operate only eight and a half days each fortnight. Coupled with short working days we<br />

calculated the redundancy to be around 25% <strong>of</strong> a standard (5 day) working week. In a<br />

larger authority this redundancy would be reduced by more accurately matching the<br />

collection requirements to the vehicle provision (and consequently reducing collection<br />

costs). However, in this case Ballymoney is able to keep costs lower than they would<br />

otherwise be by using an average crew size <strong>of</strong> driver plus one on its collection rounds.<br />

Matching crew sizes to the demands <strong>of</strong> the collection round is a useful means <strong>of</strong><br />

keeping costs in check.<br />

The leading option modelled for this work in both the Ballymoney and Coleraine<br />

studies was an option with food waste and dry recyclables both collected weekly and<br />

sorted at the kerbside onto stillage vehicles. Residual waste was kept as a fortnightly<br />

service to best maintain (in the absence <strong>of</strong> charging for waste, which is still not an<br />

option in the UK) an incentive to recycle and reduce costs <strong>of</strong> refuse collection. In<br />

these cases the figures extracted from the model are as follows:<br />

1045<br />

� Ballymoney: €90 per household per year (total collection cost);<br />

� Coleraine: €83 per household per year (total collection cost);<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> whole system costs (in other words, the costs <strong>of</strong> provision <strong>of</strong> the totals<br />

service, including costs for sorting, treatment and disposal), the figures were:<br />

� Ballymoney: €170 per household per year (total system cost);<br />

� Coleraine: €147 per household per year (total system cost);<br />

In other words, the cost <strong>of</strong> systems inclusive <strong>of</strong> a weekly food waste collection are<br />

considerably lower than the average charge in Ireland for a system providing dry<br />

recyclables only. It is not possible to explain these differences through reference to<br />

specific input factors alone, as we shall see below. 1284<br />

1284 See Eunomia (2008) Ballymoney & Coleraine Borough Councils Kerbside Collection Appraisal and<br />

Modelling Report, Report for WRAP.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


64.4 Collection Costs in England<br />

Until recently, all local authorities in England were required to report information on<br />

collection costs to the Audit Commission. These figures were <strong>of</strong>ten subject to<br />

inconsistencies in reporting and different authorities were <strong>of</strong>ten reporting systems<br />

with quite different levels <strong>of</strong> service provision (in terms <strong>of</strong>, for example, the scope and<br />

quality <strong>of</strong> recycling services). Even so, it is noteworthy that the costs <strong>of</strong> collection in<br />

the year 2005/6, when many authorities were operating recycling services, and when<br />

organic waste collections were on the increase, lay between €30 and €80 per<br />

household, with the vast majority lying between €40-€60 per household (the very<br />

lowest figures would have probably related to authorities <strong>of</strong>fering only refuse<br />

collections). 1285<br />

Figure 64-1: Collection Costs (£ per household) for English Local Authorities<br />

Cumulative Number <strong>of</strong> Authorities<br />

1046<br />

313<br />

300<br />

287<br />

274<br />

261<br />

248<br />

235<br />

222<br />

209<br />

196<br />

183<br />

170<br />

157<br />

144<br />

131<br />

118<br />

105<br />

92<br />

79<br />

66<br />

53<br />

40<br />

27<br />

14<br />

1<br />

29/09/09<br />

0.00 20.00 40.00 60.00 80.00 100.00 120.00 140.00<br />

Source: Audit Commission<br />

Collection Cost per hhld (€/hhld)<br />

1285 In 2005/6, the recycling rate for household waste in England was 27%, more or less the same as<br />

in Ireland in 2007, suggesting a broadly similar service mix, though with the absence <strong>of</strong> PBU in England<br />

suppressing performance relative to the systems on <strong>of</strong>fer.


64.5 Collection Modelling for Ireland: Assessment <strong>of</strong> Current and<br />

Potentially Achievable Collection Costs and Resulting<br />

Annual Charge Levels<br />

Although the assessment conducted in the previous sections establishes that<br />

collections in Ireland are particularly expensive compared to international experience,<br />

the full reasoning for this has not yet been explored. Data provided by a collection<br />

company operating in Ireland provides a particular insight. 1286<br />

The cost <strong>of</strong> collecting waste from households is strongly influenced by the number <strong>of</strong><br />

households the collection vehicles can serve each working day; the lower the number<br />

<strong>of</strong> households, the more vehicles (and crew) are needed to perform the service. The<br />

key detail in the data provided is the quote “The typical number <strong>of</strong> homes serviced in<br />

a single shift using a standard truck is 300.” Even in Eden, with its low (including by<br />

Irish standards) population density, the residual waste collection vehicles average<br />

700 households per day on a collection route. In a more typical situation in the UK we<br />

would expect wheeled bin residual waste collection services to achieve pass rates <strong>of</strong><br />

the order 1,200, with ranges from around 900 to 1,300 households depending on<br />

the rural/urban nature <strong>of</strong> the local authority. Daily pass rates in urban settings can be<br />

above 2,000 where the collections are entirely sack based.<br />

It is difficult to understand how conditions could so severely limit collections in the<br />

Ireland context to just 300 collections per day; there is no reason for transport<br />

logistics to be significantly different from the broad range <strong>of</strong> conditions faced in the<br />

UK (and certainly, the Irish average would not give rise to lower pass rates than in,<br />

say, Eden). One possible issue leading to this situation may be the free market<br />

approach to collection whereby collection densities are severely reduced.<br />

Using the Hermes collection model we attempted to model a collection system<br />

achieving just 300 collections per day. The model is populated with the combined<br />

experience <strong>of</strong> benchmarked collection data provided by industry collection operators<br />

from a considerable number UK authorities. Frequently, we have made use <strong>of</strong> the<br />

model in a fully transparent mode with a collection contractor watching over us.<br />

We have assumed that collection crews in Ireland have similar working practices<br />

(work time per day for example), and that logistics are broadly similar to the most<br />

challenging <strong>of</strong> those in the UK (Eden as a specific example). We have, however,<br />

adjusted the parameters in the model to account for the low levels <strong>of</strong> subscription to<br />

the services in the Ireland context by increasing the effective distance between<br />

households served (representing a lower route density). A pick up rate <strong>of</strong> 300 was<br />

modelled by assuming poor transport logistics and one in 5 households subscribing to<br />

the service. Even so, a very high collection time per property also needed to be<br />

modelled to deliver the costs which had been presented. This may be associated with<br />

the fact that a low collection density will mean collection crews are forced to<br />

frequently get in and out <strong>of</strong> the cab between pick-ups to get to the next collection<br />

1286 Greenstar (2009), The Economics <strong>of</strong> Brown Bin Domestic <strong>Waste</strong> Collection in an Irish Context<br />

1047<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


point, rather than working on foot from house to house alongside the slowly<br />

progressing vehicle.<br />

As a comparator to the system with a pass rate <strong>of</strong> 300 households per day, we<br />

modelled an alternative option whereby all households on the collection route utilised<br />

the collection system. Effectively, this gives a comparison between the two situations<br />

<strong>of</strong> “Competition in the market” (collecting from one in 5 households) and<br />

“Competition for for the market” (collection from all households). In other words, in the<br />

model we assumed to increase the number <strong>of</strong> households setting out bins in any one<br />

street by a factor <strong>of</strong> 5. This leads to much greater numbers <strong>of</strong> households served by<br />

each vehicle each day. Headline results are shown in Table 64-9.<br />

These figures correlate well with the examples provided from Northern Ireland in<br />

Section 64.3.3 <strong>of</strong> the Annexes. They show that the simple fortnightly collection service<br />

is achievable at a little over €50 per household per year. The more rapid collection<br />

operation when collecting from house to house will also be better utilising the driver<br />

plus two staffing levels on the vehicles.<br />

Table 64-9: Current Approach to Collection in Ireland compared to a Single Collection<br />

Operator (Hermes Collection Modelling)<br />

Competition Competition in in the<br />

the Competition Competition for<br />

for<br />

market<br />

market<br />

the the market market<br />

market<br />

Vehicle crewing level Driver plus 2 Driver plus 2<br />

Percentage incidence <strong>of</strong> single bin emptyings 80% 30%<br />

Percentage incidence <strong>of</strong> two bin emptyings 20% 70%<br />

Households served / vehicle / day<br />

300<br />

(for either recycling or<br />

residual collections)<br />

862 (recycling)<br />

748 (residual –<br />

more restricted by<br />

weight capacity)<br />

Number <strong>of</strong> unloads / vehicle / day 1 2<br />

Collection costs per household per annum<br />

quoted in the Irish data<br />

€137 -<br />

Calculated collection cost per household per<br />

annum (staff, vehicles, fuel, etc.)<br />

Calculated collection cost per household per<br />

€134 €52<br />

annum (staff, vehicles, fuel, etc.) plus<br />

recycling gate fees<br />

€157 €75<br />

64.6 Costs <strong>of</strong> Adding in ‘Brown Bin’ Collections<br />

A more thorough service including weekly food waste collection may be expected to<br />

significantly increase the total capture <strong>of</strong> materials for recycling, and without<br />

increasing the quantity <strong>of</strong> waste collected. Disposal costs will also be reduced. As<br />

such, as long as the costs <strong>of</strong> treatment <strong>of</strong> the collected food waste lie below those <strong>of</strong><br />

treating or disposing <strong>of</strong> residual waste, then the avoided disposal cost savings will<br />

help to fund the provision <strong>of</strong> such services. Furthermore, the introduction <strong>of</strong> food<br />

waste collection services allows for a reduction in frequency <strong>of</strong> residual waste<br />

collections. This is extremely important.<br />

In Ireland, there has been much made <strong>of</strong> the contrast between weight-based systems<br />

and other forms <strong>of</strong> PBU charging. This has been motivated, in part, by a desire to<br />

understand the performance drivers for better performing systems. What this tends to<br />

1048<br />

29/09/09


ignore, however, is that whilst costs are affected by the fate <strong>of</strong> materials in terms <strong>of</strong><br />

their management (recycling, biowaste treatment, residual waste treatment /<br />

disposal), the system costs are also influenced by the costs <strong>of</strong> collection. In this<br />

regard, a key feature <strong>of</strong> collection systems which target the most putrescible element<br />

- food waste – is that it allows for a reduction in the frequency with which households<br />

set out refuse for collection. This leads to reduced set out rates, with high quantities<br />

per set out, allowing for re-optimisation <strong>of</strong> logistics. Hence, frequency based charging<br />

systems which allow households to choose when to set out waste (as opposed to<br />

those which imply a subscription for a specified frequency – these have limited effect<br />

on behaviour at the margin) have an important role to play in optimising the costs <strong>of</strong><br />

collection logistics. It should be noted that whilst many municipalities charge only on<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> frequency, some charge on the basis <strong>of</strong> frequency and weight, which<br />

combined an incentive to reduce set out (improving collection logistics) with an<br />

incentive to generate less residual (and other charge-for fractions <strong>of</strong>) waste.<br />

In Table 64-10, we show how the costs <strong>of</strong> the modelled service (as described above)<br />

would change when a dedicated weekly collection <strong>of</strong> food waste is added to the<br />

existing service. It can be seen that the increase in cost per household is relatively<br />

small, with higher collection costs <strong>of</strong>fset by reduced costs for treatment and disposal.<br />

Table 64-10: Current Approach to Collection in Ireland compared to a Single<br />

Collection Operator (Hermes Collection Modelling)<br />

Competition ompetition for for the<br />

the Competition Competition for<br />

for<br />

market<br />

market<br />

the the market market plus<br />

weekly weekly food food food waste<br />

waste<br />

collection<br />

collection<br />

Vehicle crewing level Driver plus 2 Driver plus 2<br />

Percentage incidence <strong>of</strong> single bin emptyings 30% 30%<br />

Percentage incidence <strong>of</strong> two bin emptyings 70% 70%<br />

Households served / vehicle / day<br />

862 (recycling)<br />

748 (residual – more<br />

restricted by weight<br />

capacity)<br />

824 (recycling)<br />

742 (residual)<br />

1046 (food waste<br />

– only unloading<br />

once per day)<br />

Calculated collection cost per household per<br />

annum (staff, vehicles, fuel, etc.)<br />

Calculated collection cost per household per<br />

€52 €64<br />

annum (staff, vehicles, fuel, etc.) plus<br />

recycling gate fees<br />

€75 €87<br />

Total net collection treatment and disposal<br />

cost per household per annum*<br />

€199 €204<br />

*Assumes MRF gate fee €40/tonne, organic treatment €80/tonne, residual waste €120/tonne<br />

It should be noted that:<br />

1049<br />

1. The above analysis assumes no change in the frequency <strong>of</strong> refuse collection. If<br />

such changes occurred, costs ought to fall as round logistics are re-optimised;<br />

and<br />

2. The above analysis assumes no change in the costs as the costs <strong>of</strong> residual<br />

waste treatment / disposal increase, so the collection costs will remain<br />

unchanged, but the costs <strong>of</strong> dealing with the collected residual waste increase.<br />

<strong>International</strong> <strong>Review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Annexes


1050<br />

29/09/09<br />

Hence, the effects <strong>of</strong> an increased landfill levy would be expected to move the<br />

balance in favour <strong>of</strong> the system which sends less material to landfill.<br />

If such possibilities were factored in, the financial argument would shift more in<br />

favour <strong>of</strong> the system which includes the collection <strong>of</strong> food waste on a weekly basis.<br />

64.7 Summary<br />

It is true that Ireland is an expensive country. However, in reviewing existing<br />

household collection costs, the following seems to be the case:<br />

� The existing costs <strong>of</strong> services to householders are well above what they should<br />

be. This is clear from comparing costs with Ireland’s nearest neighbour, and<br />

when modelling collection systems using Irish input costs;<br />

� Even without considering other changes, then other things being equal, by<br />

simply moving to a ‘competition for the market’ approach, it ought to be<br />

possible to save around €80 per household per year on average, more in<br />

some case, less in others, on the costs which households are charged. This is<br />

a significant saving to Irish households and would be expected to have<br />

beneficial economic consequences far beyond the saving itself; and<br />

� The costs <strong>of</strong> adding biowaste to existing collection systems are likely to be<br />

relatively small, especially if food waste is well targeted, and households have<br />

an incentive to reduce set out frequencies for refuse.<br />

If the landfill levy increases, and if levies on other residual waste treatments are<br />

applied, then the costs <strong>of</strong> options which increase the scope for recycling and<br />

composting / digestion are likely to decline relative to the situation where no change<br />

occurs. Under such a scenario, the inclusion <strong>of</strong> biowaste collections is likely to<br />

become the cost-minimising solution. The only exceptions to this rule would be where<br />

one or more <strong>of</strong> the following apply:<br />

a) collection systems were poorly optimised<br />

b) services were procured inefficiently; and / or<br />

c) the cost <strong>of</strong> biowaste treatment relative to residual waste treatment /<br />

disposal is small. The prospects for this seem likely to be increasingly<br />

limited in future if the landfill levy is changed in line with what is<br />

proposed in the Main Report (see Annex 56.0).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!