02.03.2013 Views

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Interpreting utility functions 109<br />

Utility<br />

1.0<br />

0.8<br />

0.6<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

−10 0 10 20 30 40 50 60<br />

Money ($000)<br />

Figure 5.5 – A utility function for the conference organizer<br />

Increase<br />

in utility<br />

through<br />

winning<br />

Decrease<br />

in utility<br />

through<br />

losing the<br />

gamble<br />

Utility<br />

1.0<br />

0.8<br />

0.6<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

0<br />

0 1000 2000<br />

Money ($)<br />

Figure 5.6 – A utility function demonstrating risk aversion<br />

0.5 × $2000 + 0.5 × $0), so according to the EMV criterion he should be<br />

indifferent between keeping his money and gambling. However, when<br />

we apply the utility function to the decision we see that currently the<br />

decision maker has assets with a utility of 0.9. If he gambles he has a<br />

50% chance of increasing his assets so that their utility would increase<br />

to 1.0 and a 50% chance of ending with assets with a utility of 0. Hence<br />

the expected utility of the gamble is 0.5 × 1 + 0.5 × 0, which equals 0.5.<br />

Clearly, the certain money is more attractive than the risky option of<br />

gambling. In simple terms, even though the potential wins and losses

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!