26.03.2013 Views

Financial Articulation of a Fiduciary Duty to Bondholders with ...

Financial Articulation of a Fiduciary Duty to Bondholders with ...

Financial Articulation of a Fiduciary Duty to Bondholders with ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

THE FINANCIAL ARTICULATION OF A<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

WITH FIDUCIARY DUTIES TO<br />

STOCKHOLDERS OF THE<br />

CORPORATIONt<br />

ALBERT H. BARKEYtt<br />

I. INTRODUCTION ....................................... 48<br />

II. THE CORPORATE-FINANCE FRAMEWORK ........ 49<br />

A. CORPORATE CURRENT-MARKET-VALUE<br />

MAXIMIZATION ...................................... 49<br />

B. THE BLACK-SCHOLES CONCEPTION OF THE<br />

CORPORATION ....................................... 51<br />

C. UNANTICIPATED WEALTH EXPROPRIATIONS ......... 52<br />

D. EFFICIENT MARKET PORTFOLIOS .................... 55<br />

III. STOCKHOLDER WEALTH EXPROPRIATIONS<br />

FROM BONDHOLDERS ............................... 56<br />

A. THE EXPROPRIATION TENDENCY .................... 56<br />

B. THE BONDHOLDER-WEINBERGER HYPOTHETICAL ..... 58<br />

1. Factual Aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger .................. 58<br />

2. Dicta Aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger .................... 60<br />

3. The Bondholder-Weinberger Hypothetical:<br />

Facts ............................................. 61<br />

IV. A FIDUCIARY LAW SOLUTION ...................... 64<br />

A. THE BONDHOLDER-WEINBERGER HYPOTHETICAL:<br />

A RGUMENTS ......................................... 64<br />

1. Deb<strong>to</strong>r Speaks ................................ 64<br />

2. Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs Speak ................... 67<br />

3. Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs Speak ................. 67<br />

B. W HAT IS FAIR? ...................................... 72<br />

V. THE NEW FIDUCIARY ARTICULATION ............. 74<br />

A. GLOBAL WEALTH MAXIMIZATION .................... 74<br />

B. PROCEDURAL FAIRNESS .............................. 78<br />

1. Additional Factual Aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger... 78<br />

t Copyright 1986 by Albert H. Barkey.<br />

tt Member, New York bar; private practice, Bronx, N.Y.; B.A., 1970, New York<br />

University; M.B.A., 1972, New York University; M.P.A., 1979, Mt. Sinai School <strong>of</strong><br />

Medicine, Baruch College; J.D., 1980, New York Law School; A.P.C., 1981, New York<br />

University; Diploma, 1983, United States Army Command and General Staff Officer<br />

Course; LL.M., 1984, New York University.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

2. Additional Dicta Aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger ..... 80<br />

3. The Procedural-Fairness Structure ........... 81<br />

VI. CONCLUSION .......................................... 83<br />

I. INTRODUCTION<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

The premise <strong>of</strong> this Article is that there should be coherence between<br />

the theoretical structures <strong>of</strong> corporate finance and corporate<br />

fiduciary law.' Because corporate finance is grounded in science, and<br />

because corporate fiduciary law is grounded in public policy, this Article<br />

views corporate fiduciary law as a corrective <strong>of</strong> corporate-financial<br />

anomalies. Under this view, the identification <strong>of</strong> a corporatefinancial<br />

anomaly points <strong>to</strong> the superimposition <strong>of</strong> corporate fiduciary<br />

law on that anomaly.<br />

A central dogma <strong>of</strong> corporate practice views the for-pr<strong>of</strong>it corporation<br />

as properly seeking <strong>to</strong> maximize the value <strong>of</strong> its s<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>with</strong>out<br />

direct regard for the value <strong>of</strong> other classes <strong>of</strong> its securities. 2 This<br />

dogma operates through three assumptions: (1) that a managerial fiduciary<br />

duty <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ckholders does not also imply corresponding duties<br />

<strong>to</strong> the corporation's other classes <strong>of</strong> securityholders, 3 (2) that equitable<br />

ownership <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets by s<strong>to</strong>ckholders does not<br />

also imply corresponding ownerships by the corporation's other<br />

classes <strong>of</strong> securityholders, 4 and (3) that maximizing the value <strong>of</strong> the<br />

corporation's s<strong>to</strong>ck is equivalent <strong>to</strong> maximizing the value <strong>of</strong> the corporation's<br />

assets. 5<br />

This Article challenges this central dogma and its operational assumptions<br />

on grounds <strong>of</strong> incongruity <strong>with</strong> and derivative unfairness<br />

under the established theoretical structure <strong>of</strong> corporate finance.<br />

1. This Article develops the corporate law implications <strong>of</strong> the Black-Scholes option-pricing<br />

framework. See generally A. Barkey, The Black-Scholes Redistribution<br />

Argument in the Statu<strong>to</strong>ry-<strong>Fiduciary</strong> Context <strong>of</strong> Weinberger v. UOP, Inc. (Dec. 21,<br />

1983) (limited distribution manuscript) (available from the New York University<br />

School <strong>of</strong> Law).<br />

2. See Brudney, Equal Treatment <strong>of</strong> Shareholders in Corporate Distributions<br />

and Reorganizations, 71 CALIF. L. REV. 1072, 1089 n.42 (1983); Easterbrook & Fischel,<br />

The Proper Role <strong>of</strong> a Target's Management in Responding <strong>to</strong> a Tender Offer, 94 HARV.<br />

L. REV. 1161, 1191 (1981); Prokesch, Merger Wave: How S<strong>to</strong>ck and Bonds Fare, N.Y.<br />

Times, Jan. 7, 1986, at 1, col. 1; Norris, Not the Preferred Treatment, BARRON'S, June<br />

17, 1985, at 45, col. 1.<br />

3. See Broad v. Rockwell Int'l Corp., 642 F.2d 929, 958-59 (5th Cir.), cert. denied,<br />

454 U.S. 965 (1981); Norte & Co. v. Manor Healthcare Corp., Nos. 6827, 6831, at 6-7<br />

(Del. Ch. Nov. 21, 1985) (available on LEXIS, States library, Del file).<br />

4. See Norte & Co., at 6. Gibson & Campbell, Fundamental Law for Takeovers,<br />

39 Bus. LAW. 1551, 1551 (1984).<br />

5. See Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 2, at 1190-91; Fischel, The Business<br />

Judgment Rule and the Trans Union Case, 40 Bus. LAW. 1437, 1442-43 (1985); Warden,<br />

The Boardroom as a War Room: The Real World Applications <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Duty</strong> <strong>of</strong> Care and<br />

the <strong>Duty</strong> <strong>of</strong> Loyalty, 40 BUs. LAW. 1431, 1431 (1985).


1986] FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

Also, this Article sketches a new line <strong>of</strong> development for corporate<br />

law based upon a new fiduciary articulation which reconciles the corporate<br />

conflict <strong>of</strong> interest between "bondholders" and s<strong>to</strong>ckholders.<br />

Because <strong>of</strong> the national influence <strong>of</strong> Delaware's law <strong>of</strong> corporations 7<br />

and because <strong>of</strong> the elegance <strong>of</strong> the generalized fact pattern in Weinberger<br />

v. UOP, Inc. ,8 this Article employs aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger in an<br />

illustrative discussion <strong>of</strong> the new fiduciary articulation.<br />

II. THE CORPORATE-FINANCE FRAMEWORK<br />

A. CORPORATE CURRENT-MARKET-VALUE MAXIMIZATION<br />

An operating decision "efficiently" uses corporate assets when it<br />

maximizes their present value; 9 an operating decision "wastes" corporate<br />

assets when it reduces their present value.' 0 Corporate "financing<br />

decisions" are decisions regarding methods <strong>of</strong> providing capital <strong>to</strong><br />

the corporation." Corporate debt is "risky" when there is a chance<br />

that the corporation might not be able <strong>to</strong> make full payments on all<br />

its debt promises. 12 A "side payment" is a transfer <strong>of</strong> wealth between<br />

classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders.1 3<br />

A central problem for the corporation is that there is, in general,<br />

no way <strong>of</strong> directly constructing managerial objectives from the diverse<br />

preferences <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders. 14 This<br />

6. The term "bond" is used herein for all debt securities. See AM. BAR FOUND.,<br />

COMMENTARIES ON INDENTURES 7 n.3, 8 (1971). For a discussion <strong>of</strong> the "investment<br />

contract" definition <strong>of</strong> a security, see Schneider, The Elusive Definition <strong>of</strong> a Security,<br />

14 REV. SEC. REG. 981 (1981) (discussing the definition <strong>of</strong> security under the federal<br />

securities laws). For a discussion <strong>of</strong> inves<strong>to</strong>r interest in bonds, see Ehrlich, The Smorgasbord<br />

<strong>of</strong> Bonds: Something For Almost Every Palate, Bus. WK., -, 122 (Dec. 30,<br />

1985). The distinction between debt and equity is irrelevant <strong>to</strong> the conflict <strong>of</strong> classes <strong>of</strong><br />

securityholders having nested claims on the corporation's assets and cash flow. The<br />

term "s<strong>to</strong>cks" is used herein as a parallel <strong>to</strong> the term "bonds," and means "shares <strong>of</strong><br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck" or "s<strong>to</strong>ck."<br />

7. See Black, Jr., A National Law <strong>of</strong> Takeovers Evolves in Delaware, Legal<br />

Times, Nov. 25, 1985, at 6, col. 1.<br />

8. 457 A.2d 701, 704-08 (Del. 1983).<br />

9. In other words, the decision selects the use <strong>with</strong> the largest present value <strong>of</strong><br />

its expected value. See E. FAMA & M. MILLER, THE THEORY OF FINANCE 180 (1972).<br />

The expected (mean) value is the sum over all outcomes <strong>of</strong> each outcome times the<br />

chance <strong>of</strong> that outcome occurring. See id.<br />

10. In other words, the decision selects a use <strong>with</strong> a present value <strong>of</strong> its expected<br />

value which is less than the present value <strong>of</strong> the assets. See Stiglitz, Some Aspects <strong>of</strong><br />

the Pure Theory <strong>of</strong> Corporate Finance: Bankruptcies and Take-Overs, 3 BELL J. ECON.<br />

& MGMT. SCI. 458, 460-62 (1972).<br />

11. See E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 109, 150-57.<br />

12. Id. at 152 n.5, 179.<br />

13. See id. at 179-80. A "side payment" is a payment made on the side.<br />

14. Id. at 67-68 (discussing Arrow's proposition stated in K. ARROW, SOCIAL<br />

CHOICE AND INDIVIDUAL VALUES 48-59 (2d ed. 1963)). See generally J. KELLY, ARROW<br />

IMPOSSIBILITY THEOREMS (1978).


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

problem is solved, in general, by a rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-marketvalue<br />

maximization15 which states that "given perfect capital markets,<br />

optimal operating decisions for a firm at any point in time involve<br />

maximizing the market value <strong>of</strong> those securities outstanding<br />

before the operating decision is made.' 6 If the corporation complies<br />

<strong>with</strong> this rule and efficiently uses corporate assets, then all <strong>of</strong> the<br />

corporation's securityholders agree on the corporation's operating decisions<br />

and are indifferent about the corporation's financing decisions.<br />

17 Therefore, this rule is a ground for independent pr<strong>of</strong>essional<br />

decision-making by corporate <strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs. 18<br />

An anomaly in this rule occurs when there exists risky debt<br />

<strong>with</strong>out side payments because <strong>of</strong> the possibility that an operating<br />

decision which efficiently uses corporate assets <strong>to</strong> maximize the current<br />

market value <strong>of</strong> the corporation might not also maximize the<br />

separate current market values <strong>of</strong> the corporation's bonds and<br />

s<strong>to</strong>cks. 19 The significance <strong>of</strong> this anomaly depends on the facts <strong>of</strong><br />

each case. 20 The manifestation <strong>of</strong> this anomaly through a corporate<br />

policy <strong>of</strong> inefficient use <strong>of</strong> corporate assets is rectified by the capital<br />

market: capital market anticipation <strong>of</strong> such a policy is reflected in<br />

the market values <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securities, and such a policy<br />

makes a corporate takeover pr<strong>of</strong>itable under a takeover policy <strong>of</strong> effi-<br />

2 1<br />

cient use <strong>of</strong> corporate assets.<br />

When maximizing the current market value <strong>of</strong> the corporation<br />

does not also maximize the current market value <strong>of</strong> its s<strong>to</strong>cks, then<br />

the current market value <strong>of</strong> the corporation's s<strong>to</strong>cks can be maximized<br />

by: (1) inefficiently using corporate assets, or (2) efficiently<br />

using corporate assets <strong>with</strong> a bondholder-<strong>to</strong>-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder side payment.<br />

22 If there is a significant chance <strong>of</strong> corporate bankruptcy, then<br />

these means respectively transform in<strong>to</strong>: (1) wasting corporate assets,<br />

or (2) preserving corporate assets <strong>with</strong> a bondholder-<strong>to</strong>-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder<br />

side payment. 23<br />

15. E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 69-73. For a discussion <strong>of</strong> unanimity<br />

theorems, see De Angelo, Competition and Unanimity, 71 AM. ECON. REV. 18, -<br />

(1981).<br />

16. E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 176. For a discussion <strong>of</strong> perfect capital<br />

markets, see id. at 3-41, 176-78.<br />

17. Id. at 69, 145, 176.<br />

18. See id. at 69, 74-75.<br />

19. Id. at 71, n.4, 178-80.<br />

20. Jensen & Meckling, Theory <strong>of</strong> the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs,<br />

and Ownership Structure, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 305, 337 n.43 (1976). See W. KLEIN, BUSINESS<br />

ORGANIZATION AND FINANCE 190 (1980).<br />

21. Fama, The Effects <strong>of</strong> a Firm's Investment and Financing Decisions on the<br />

Welfare <strong>of</strong> its Security Holders, 68 AM. ECON. REV. 272, 282-84 (1978).<br />

22. See E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 180.<br />

23. See Stiglitz, supra note 10, at 460-62.


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

B. THE BLACK-SCHOLES CONCEPTION OF THE CORPORATION<br />

An "option" is "[a] contract giving its holder the right <strong>to</strong> buy or<br />

sell... [something] at a predetermined price and predetermined time<br />

period. ' 2 4 A "call option" is an option <strong>to</strong> buy. 25 A "compound option"<br />

is "an option on an option. ' 2 6 "Synergy" means that the <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

effect <strong>of</strong> a combination is greater than the sum <strong>of</strong> the individual effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> the components <strong>of</strong> that combination before that combination<br />

occurred. A "nonsynergistic merger" is a merger <strong>with</strong>out corporate<br />

market value synergy: the market value <strong>of</strong> the combined corporation<br />

equals the sum <strong>of</strong> the premerger market values <strong>of</strong> the corporations<br />

merging. 27 An "efficient capital market" is a capital market in which<br />

"any new information reaching the market concerning asset values is<br />

immediately impounded in<strong>to</strong> security prices.128 The "debt capacity"<br />

<strong>of</strong> a corporation is the pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> the maximum market value <strong>of</strong> bonds<br />

that the corporation can have outstanding in the capital market for a<br />

2 9<br />

range <strong>of</strong> interest rates.<br />

Aris<strong>to</strong>tle said that "the house is there that men may live in it,<br />

but it is also there because the builders have laid one s<strong>to</strong>ne upon an-<br />

other. ' 30 The Black-Scholes option-pricing framework is an example<br />

<strong>of</strong> such a duality because it scientifically describes both option prices<br />

and the bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder corporate-financial mechanism. 31<br />

This framework is based on postulates regarding the capital<br />

24. Dow JONES & CO., INC., THE ABC's OF OPTION TRADING 30 (1981).<br />

25. Id. at 29.<br />

26. K. Shastri, Valuing Corporate Securities: Some Effects <strong>of</strong> Mergers by Exchange<br />

Offers 10 (University <strong>of</strong> Pittsburgh WP-517 Jan. 1982).<br />

27. See Galai & Masulis, The Option Pricing Model and the Risk Fac<strong>to</strong>r <strong>of</strong> S<strong>to</strong>ck, 3<br />

J. FIN. ECON. 53, 66 & n.38, 68 (1976).<br />

28. Id. at 72. See generally E. FAMA, FOUNDATIONS OF FINANCE 133-68 (1976) (discussing<br />

four models <strong>of</strong> efficient capital market equilibrium).<br />

29. See Staple<strong>to</strong>n, Mergers, Debt Capacity, and the Valuation <strong>of</strong> Corporate Loans,<br />

in MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS 9, 9-10, 14 (1982) (discussing the Black-Scholes option<br />

pricing framework).<br />

30. D. THOMPSON, ON GROWTH AND FORM 6 (1942) (providing a statement <strong>of</strong> the<br />

parable).<br />

31. See Smith, Jr., Option Pricing: A Review, 3 J. FIN. ECON. 3, 4 (1976). The<br />

Black-Scholes option pricing model is the limiting case <strong>of</strong> the binomial option pricing<br />

formula. Cox, Ross & Rubinstein, Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach, 7 J. FIN.<br />

ECON. 229, 250-54 (1979). The model "seeks <strong>to</strong> price the securities whose values are<br />

contingent upon the value <strong>of</strong> the underlying asset." Hsia, Coherence <strong>of</strong> the Modern<br />

Theories <strong>of</strong> Finance, 1981 FIN. REV. 27, 36. The model values a call option when its<br />

underlying asset does not make asset distributions before the call's maturity. Smith,<br />

Jr., supra, at 4-5, 25 (discussing European and nondividend-paying American calls). A<br />

combination model values a call option when its underlying asset makes known future<br />

asset distributions before the call's maturity. Roll, An Analytic Valuation Formula<br />

for Unprotected American Call Options on S<strong>to</strong>cks <strong>with</strong> Known Dividends, 5 J. FIN.<br />

ECON. 251, - (1977). A compound model values a call option on a call option. See<br />

Geske, The Valuation <strong>of</strong> Corporate Liabilities as Compound Options, 12 J. FIN. &<br />

QUAN. ANAL. 541, - (1977).


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

market, 32 and its usefulness cannot be evaluated independently <strong>of</strong><br />

the capital market efficiency on which it is grounded. 33<br />

In the Black-Scholes scientific conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation, the<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholders own a call option, <strong>with</strong> operational control, on the bondholders'<br />

ownership <strong>of</strong> the corporate assets and cash flow. 34 Under<br />

this view, there is a dynamic mathematical "distribution <strong>of</strong> ownership<br />

between the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders and bondholders. '35 The corporation's<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck is a compound option when the corporation issues finite-maturity<br />

risky coupon bonds; 3 6 the s<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>of</strong> the combined corporation in a<br />

nonsynergistic merger is a compound option. 37 Also, in general, corporate<br />

debt capacity is synergistic in nonsynergistic mergers. 38<br />

C. UNANTICIPATED WEALTH EXPROPRIATIONS<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

In general: "Bond protective contractual provisions" seek <strong>to</strong> fix<br />

existing corporate conditions (under which original bond purchase<br />

prices and bond interest rates are fixed) in order <strong>to</strong> restrict possible<br />

corporate acts which might adversely affect the value <strong>of</strong> their bonds,<br />

and they seek <strong>to</strong> force a preferred remedy (such as bond buyback,<br />

bond renegotiation, or corporate bankruptcy)when the value <strong>of</strong> their<br />

bonds significantly deteriorates. 39 The contract (termed on "indenture")<br />

containing these provisions (termed "covenants") is negotiated<br />

between the corporation representing the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders who control it<br />

and a separate corporation (termed a "trustee") representing the<br />

bondholders. 40 "Bond pricing" is the coordinate determination<br />

32. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 54-55. "Subsequent modification <strong>of</strong> the basic<br />

Black-Scholes model ... shows that the analysis is quite robust <strong>with</strong> respect <strong>to</strong> relaxation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the basic assumptions under which the model is derived. No single<br />

assumption seems crucial <strong>to</strong> the analysis." Smith, Jr., supra note 31, at 4.<br />

33. See Bhattacharya, Empirical Properties <strong>of</strong> the Black-Scholes Formula Under<br />

Ideal Conditions, 15 J. FIN. & QUAN. ANAL. 1081, 1081, 1095 (1980).<br />

34. Black & Scholes, The Pricing <strong>of</strong> Options and Corporate Liabilities, 81 J. POL.<br />

ECON. 637, 649-52 (1973); Staple<strong>to</strong>n, supra note 29, at 9.<br />

35. Smith, Jr., supra note 31, at 43.<br />

36. Geske, supra note 31, at 542 (stating: "At every coupon date, until the final<br />

payments, the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders have the option <strong>of</strong> buying the next coupon or forfeiting the<br />

firm <strong>to</strong> the bondholders.").<br />

37. K. Shastri, supra note 26, at 10. "The valuation equations ... collapse <strong>to</strong> the<br />

Black-Scholes equation in three special cases." Id. at 14.<br />

38. In other words, the debt capacity <strong>of</strong> the combined corporation in a nonsynergistic<br />

merger is generally greater than the sum <strong>of</strong> the premerger debt capacities <strong>of</strong> the<br />

corporations merging. Staple<strong>to</strong>n, supra note 29, at 15, 18, 24-25.<br />

39. See Black & Cox, Valuing Corporate Securities: Some Effects <strong>of</strong> Bond Indenture<br />

Provisions, 31 J. FIN. 351, 355-57 (1976); Brody, Controversial Issue, BARRON's,<br />

Sept. 19, 1983, at 15, 19, col. 1; Jensen & Meckling, supra note 20, at 337-38; Smith, Jr.<br />

& Warner, On <strong>Financial</strong> Contracting: An Analysis <strong>of</strong> Bond Covenants, 7 J. FIN. ECON.<br />

117, 119, 153 (1979).<br />

40. See AMER. BAR FOUND., supra note 6; AM. BAR ASS'N COMM. ON DEV. IN BUSI-<br />

NESS FINANCING, SECTION OF CORP., BANKING AND Bus. L., Model Simplified Inden-


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

regarding a bond's purchase, interest, and redemption payments.<br />

"States <strong>of</strong> nature" are eventualities or possible future outcomes. "Variance"<br />

is a measure <strong>of</strong> dispersion around the expected (mean) value<br />

<strong>of</strong> outcomes. 41<br />

The anomaly in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization-generalized<br />

<strong>to</strong> conditions wherein the current market<br />

value <strong>of</strong> the corporation increases, remains the same, or decreases-is<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> the bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder corporate conflict <strong>of</strong> interest.<br />

42 Bond protective contractual provisions are a signal (indica<strong>to</strong>r)<br />

<strong>to</strong> the capital market that the s<strong>to</strong>ckholder-controlled corporation will<br />

conform <strong>to</strong> the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization<br />

and efficiently use corporate assets. In general, this signal is reflected<br />

in the market values <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securities. 43<br />

When the original bondholders lend money <strong>to</strong> a firm, they<br />

take cognizance not only <strong>of</strong> the returns in the different<br />

states <strong>of</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> the firm under its present management<br />

but also <strong>of</strong> the chance <strong>of</strong> a take-over bid, a new management<br />

which would make an alternative set <strong>of</strong> decisions. They<br />

must take in<strong>to</strong> account all the possible take-over bids, and<br />

the resulting dispersion in the possible returns from the firm<br />

4 4<br />

may be very large indeed.<br />

Thus, ex ante contractual specificities in bond pricing might be ex<br />

post imperfect-even if they are ex ante perfect-because <strong>of</strong> unanticipated<br />

changes in facts, possibilities, and probabilities affecting the<br />

value <strong>of</strong> the bonds. 45 Bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder side payments which<br />

are caused by such contractually unanticipated changes are<br />

ture, 38 Bus. LAW. 741, 751, 758-62 (1983); Smith, Case & Morison, The Trust Indenture<br />

Act <strong>of</strong> 1939 Needs No Conflict <strong>of</strong> Interest Revision, 35 Bus. LAW. 161, 163-66 (1979);<br />

Stark, The Trust Indenture Act <strong>of</strong> 1939 in the Proposed Federal Securities Code, 32<br />

VAND. L. REV. 527, 530, 537 (1979); Note, The Trust Indenture Act <strong>of</strong> 1939: The Corporate<br />

Trustee As Credi<strong>to</strong>r, 24 UCLA L. REV. 131, 131 & n.3 (1976).<br />

41. M. SPIEGEL, PROBABILITY AND STATISTIcs 78 (1975).<br />

42. See E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 152 n.5, 179-80; Galai & Masulis,<br />

supra note 27, at 62-71; Stiglitz, supra note 10, at 460-62.<br />

43. Scott, Jr., On The Theory Of Conglomerate Mergers, 32 J. FIN. 1235, 1241<br />

(1977). See Fama, supra note 21, at 283-84; Gilson & Kraakman, The Mechanisms <strong>of</strong><br />

Market Efficiency, 70 VA. L. REV. 549, 613-14 (1984). Cf. Stiglitz, supra note 10, at 461<br />

n.l1 (stating that "a firm which must have continual recourse <strong>to</strong> the capital market<br />

must continue <strong>to</strong> worry about returns in all states [<strong>of</strong> nature]").<br />

44. Stiglitz, supra note 10, at 473.<br />

45. See id.; Farrell, Takeovers and Buyouts Clobber Blue-Chip <strong>Bondholders</strong>, Bus.<br />

WK. 113, 114 (Nov. 11, 1985) (statement <strong>of</strong> Mr. Harold H. Goldberg, Senior Vice-President,<br />

Moody's Inves<strong>to</strong>rs Service, Inc.) (stating: "There's no way <strong>to</strong> anticipate a [bondrating]<br />

downgrade from a possible future [corporate] restructuring while remaining<br />

fair <strong>to</strong> a company's current prospects."); (paraphrase <strong>of</strong> statement <strong>of</strong> Mr. Frederick H.<br />

Joseph, Vice-chairman and Chief Executive Officer, Drexel Burnham Lambert, Inc.)<br />

(stating that "there's no protective covenant that a good lawyer can't get around.").<br />

For a discussion <strong>of</strong> bond ratings, see O'Neill & Weinberger, Corporate Restructurings<br />

and Bond Ratings, 17 MERG. & AcQ. 36, - (1982) (discussing the approach <strong>of</strong> Standard


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

"unanticipated wealth expropriations" because they are a consequence<br />

<strong>of</strong> the failure <strong>of</strong> contractual ordering <strong>to</strong> provide perfect protection<br />

for bondholders' and/or s<strong>to</strong>ckholders' wealth. 46<br />

Because the variables in the Black-Scholes option-pricing framework<br />

admit <strong>of</strong> changes which are not contractually anticipated by<br />

bond pricing in the capital market, "unanticipated changes in any <strong>of</strong><br />

these variables can affect the market value <strong>of</strong> the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders' and<br />

bondholders' claims" evaluated under this framework. 47 For example,<br />

the Black-Scholes option-pricing framework has shown that in a<br />

nonsynergistic merger<br />

between two firms containing only pure coupon bonds and<br />

equity in their capital structure, the possible wealth transfer<br />

effects are:<br />

(i) from s<strong>to</strong>ckholders <strong>to</strong> short and long-term<br />

debtholders<br />

(ii) from s<strong>to</strong>ckholders and long-term debtholders <strong>to</strong><br />

short-term debtholders<br />

(iii) from s<strong>to</strong>ckholders and short-term debtholders <strong>to</strong><br />

long-term debtholders<br />

and (iv) from long-term debtholders <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ckholders and<br />

short-term debtholders.<br />

The above wealth-expropriation effects . . . carry<br />

through even when the bonds receive coupon payments and<br />

when the variance <strong>of</strong> returns on the merged firm changes after<br />

retirement <strong>of</strong> short-term debt. 48<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

Bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder unanticipated wealth expropriations might<br />

also occur in corporate divestitures, issuances and retirements <strong>of</strong><br />

bonds and s<strong>to</strong>cks, spin-<strong>of</strong>fs, etc. 49<br />

Unanticipated wealth expropriations can be neutralized by side<br />

payments among the classes <strong>of</strong> securityholders involved in the expropriations.<br />

5 0 Inves<strong>to</strong>rs are economically unaffected by an unanticipated<br />

wealth expropriation when they own equal proportions <strong>of</strong> the<br />

classes <strong>of</strong> securities affected by that expropriation. 5 '<br />

& Poor's Corp.); Willoughby, Uncertain Umpires, FORBES, -, 131 (June 16, 1986) (discussing<br />

shaky bond ratings based on payment insurance).<br />

46. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 55 n.5, 61-62, 68 n.43.<br />

47. Smith, Jr., supra note 31, at 45.<br />

48. K. Shastri, supra note 26, at 3.<br />

49. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 62-66, 69-71.<br />

50. Id. at 55 n.5, 62, 70; K. Shastri, supra note 26, at 55-56. See E. FAMA & M.<br />

MILLER, supra note 9, at 71-72 n.4, 155 n.10, 179. These side payments include new unanticipated<br />

wealth expropriations. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 69, 70, 78-79.<br />

51. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 62 & nn.27-28.


1986] FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

D. EFFICIENT MARKET PORTFOLIOS<br />

Risk (variance) has two components: diversifiable risk (which is<br />

risk that can be eliminated by investment diversification) and covariance<br />

risk (which is the nondiversifiable residual risk). 5 2 A "riskaverse"<br />

inves<strong>to</strong>r eschews specified risk (the variance <strong>of</strong> outcomes in<br />

an investment) in favor <strong>of</strong> its economically equivalent certainty (the<br />

expected value <strong>of</strong> the investment), whereas a "risk-liking" inves<strong>to</strong>r<br />

seeks such risk as against such certainty. A "risk-neutral" inves<strong>to</strong>r is<br />

indifferent <strong>to</strong> such risk or <strong>to</strong> such certainty. 53<br />

The intertemporal capital-asset-pricing model 54 can be developed<br />

from the addition <strong>of</strong> three postulates <strong>to</strong> those <strong>of</strong> the Black-Scholes<br />

option-pricing framework: 55 (1) all inves<strong>to</strong>rs are risk-averse, 5 6 (2) all<br />

inves<strong>to</strong>rs have restricted mathematical forms <strong>of</strong> risk aversion and/or<br />

all investments have restricted mathematical forms <strong>of</strong> returns 5 7 and<br />

(3) all inves<strong>to</strong>rs simultaneously possess identical investment facts and<br />

5 8<br />

beliefs. In the intertemporal capital-asset-pricing model, all inves<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

agree on the price <strong>of</strong> instantaneous covariance risk 5 9 and all in-<br />

ves<strong>to</strong>rs own (in varying quantities) equal proportions <strong>of</strong> each<br />

6 0<br />

corporation's securities invested in.<br />

"[O]ptimum portfolios for all inves<strong>to</strong>rs" are combinations <strong>of</strong> a<br />

52. See generally H. MARKOWITZ, PORTFOLIO SELECTION - (1959). "Covariance<br />

risk" is the marginal change in portfolio risk caused by an asset.<br />

53. E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 200-03; Posner, The Rights <strong>of</strong> Credi<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

<strong>of</strong> AJffiliated Corporations, 43 U. CHI. L. REv. 499, 502 nn.8-9 (1976). For a discussion<br />

regarding risk-oriented states <strong>of</strong> mind, see K. ARROW, ESSAYS IN THE THEORY OF RISK-<br />

BEARING 90-119 (1970); H. MARKOWITZ, supra note 52, at 205-73; Friedman & Savage,<br />

The Utility Analysis <strong>of</strong> Choices Involving Risk, 56 J. POL. ECON. 279, - (1948) (expected<br />

utility maximization <strong>with</strong> a concave-convex von Neumann-Morgenstern utility<br />

function); and Pratt, Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large, 32 ECONOMETRICA<br />

122, - (1964).<br />

54. The intertemporal capital-asset-pricing model is a special case <strong>of</strong> the arbitrage<br />

theory <strong>of</strong> capital asset pricing. See Ross, The Arbitrage Theory <strong>of</strong> Capital Asset Pricing,<br />

13 J. ECON. THEORY 341, - (1976). Its usefulness cannot be evaluated independently<br />

<strong>of</strong> the capital market efficiency on which it is grounded. See Roll, A Critique <strong>of</strong><br />

the Asset Pricing Theory's Tests, 4 J. FIN. ECON. 129, - (1977). See generally Mer<strong>to</strong>n,<br />

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model, 41 ECONOMETRICA 867, - (1973).<br />

55. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 54-55 & nn.4-6. See generally Hsia,<br />

supra note 31, at - (integrating the option-pricing model <strong>with</strong> the capital-asset-pricing<br />

model, the time-state preference model, and the Modigliani-Miller propositions).<br />

56. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 54.<br />

57. See Cass & Stiglitz, The Structure <strong>of</strong> Inves<strong>to</strong>r Preferences and Asset Returns,<br />

and Separability in Portfolio Allocation: A Contribution <strong>to</strong> the Pure Theory <strong>of</strong> Mutual<br />

Funds, 2 J. ECON. THEORY 122 (1970); Ross, Mutual Fund Separation in <strong>Financial</strong> Theory<br />

- The Separating Distributions, 17 J. ECON. THEORY 254, (1978).<br />

58. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 54. See generally Stiglitz, supra note 10, at<br />

464 (stating: "It is the latter assumption that we find most objectionable.").<br />

59. See Jensen, Capital Markets: Theory and Evidence, 3 BELL J. ECON. & MGMT.<br />

Sci. 357, 362-63, 394-95 (1972).<br />

60. E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 289.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

riskless asset <strong>with</strong> an efficient market portfolio which "consists <strong>of</strong> all<br />

assets in the market, each entering the portfolio <strong>with</strong> weight equal <strong>to</strong><br />

the ratio <strong>of</strong> its <strong>to</strong>tal market value <strong>to</strong> the <strong>to</strong>tal market value <strong>of</strong> all assets."<br />

61 These combinations <strong>of</strong> a riskless asset and the efficient market<br />

portfolio vary in accordance <strong>with</strong> each inves<strong>to</strong>r's degree <strong>of</strong> risk<br />

aversion. 62<br />

Inves<strong>to</strong>rs are indifferent <strong>to</strong> all wealth expropriations<br />

<strong>with</strong>in the efficient market portfolio because all inves<strong>to</strong>rs own equal<br />

proportions <strong>of</strong> all assets <strong>with</strong>in the efficient market portfolio. 63<br />

III. STOCKHOLDER WEALTH EXPROPRIATIONS FROM<br />

BONDHOLDERS<br />

A. THE EXPROPRIATION TENDENCY<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

In the Black-Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation, the exercise<br />

price on the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders' call option regarding corporate assets and<br />

cash flow is the payment due the bondholders. 64 Assume that corporate<br />

assets (including cash flow) have equal chances for values which<br />

are equally greater than and less than their expected value.<br />

In the case <strong>of</strong> two classes <strong>of</strong> corporate securities such as bonds<br />

and s<strong>to</strong>cks, the Black-Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation might be<br />

thought <strong>of</strong> as s<strong>to</strong>ckholders owning the corporate form (call option on<br />

the corporate substance) and bondholders owning the corporate substance<br />

(assets and cash flow). The mechanism <strong>of</strong> this form-substance<br />

distinction-and more generally <strong>of</strong> the nesting <strong>of</strong> ownerships <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

assets and cash flow by classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders-involves<br />

an inherent corporate tendency for unanticipated<br />

wealth expropriations from bondholders which the classical conception<br />

<strong>of</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ckholder equitable ownership <strong>of</strong> the corporate substance<br />

fails <strong>to</strong> discern. 65<br />

61. Id.<br />

62. Id. If inves<strong>to</strong>rs also own nonmarketable assets, then inves<strong>to</strong>rs own combinations<br />

<strong>of</strong> a riskless asset <strong>with</strong> both marketable and nonmarketable assets. Jensen,<br />

supra note 59, at 380-82 (discussing Mayers' model). A portfolio having zero covariance<br />

<strong>with</strong> the market portfolio can be substituted for the riskless asset. Black, Capital Market<br />

Equilibrium <strong>with</strong> Restricted Borrowing, 45 J. Bus. 444, - (1972).<br />

63. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 62 & n.27, 71 n.50. Inves<strong>to</strong>r indifference <strong>to</strong><br />

such wealth expropriation exists only when all inves<strong>to</strong>rs own efficient market portfolios<br />

or when all inves<strong>to</strong>rs in the classes <strong>of</strong> securities involved in the expropriations own<br />

equal proportions <strong>of</strong> those securities. Id. at 62 & nn.27-28.<br />

64. See supra notes 34-37 and accompanying text. The appropriate time when<br />

value adjustment would be made is upon comparing debt payments <strong>with</strong> corporate<br />

returns.<br />

65. The classical conception's objection that it cannot be explained why corporate<br />

events such as takeovers might be deleterious <strong>to</strong> bondholders, see Easterbrook & Fischel,<br />

supra note 2, at 1190, is overcome by the explanation <strong>of</strong> the generalized anomaly<br />

in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization intensified through the<br />

expropriation tendency by risk-averse s<strong>to</strong>ckholders.


1986] FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

A risk-averse s<strong>to</strong>ckholder equitable owner <strong>of</strong> such corporate assets<br />

would not seek unanticipated increases in their instantaneous variance<br />

because increased variance equally increases the chances for<br />

decreased values along <strong>with</strong> increased values. 66 However, a riskaverse<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholder equitable owner <strong>of</strong> a call option on such assets<br />

would seek, ceteris paribus, 67 unanticipated increases in their instantaneous<br />

variance when the call option's exercise price is (1) greater<br />

than the expected value <strong>of</strong> such assets, because increased variance increases<br />

the chances for exercising the call option, 68 and (2) less than<br />

the expected value <strong>of</strong> such assets while the corporation's asset instantaneous<br />

covariance risk and capital-structure-unaffected market<br />

value 69 are constant, 70 because increased variance decreases the instantaneous<br />

covariance risk <strong>of</strong> the corporation's s<strong>to</strong>cks and increases<br />

their market value. 71 Situation (1) admits <strong>of</strong> unanticipated wealth<br />

expropriations from bondholders through waste <strong>of</strong> corporate assets<br />

because there is a significant chance <strong>of</strong> corporate bankruptcy when<br />

the call option's exercise price is greater than the expected value <strong>of</strong><br />

the corporation's assets. 72 Situation (2) admits <strong>of</strong> unanticipated<br />

wealth expropriations from bondholders through: (a) wealth redistributions<br />

because an increase in the s<strong>to</strong>cks' market value correspondingly<br />

decreases the bonds' market value, 73 and (b) inefficient use <strong>of</strong><br />

corporate assets because <strong>of</strong> the chance "that a more pr<strong>of</strong>itable<br />

66. A risk-averse (decreasing positive marginal utility <strong>of</strong> wealth <strong>with</strong> increasing<br />

wealth) individual would not desire <strong>to</strong> participate in an investment having an equal<br />

chance <strong>of</strong> equal gain or loss because the increase in utility from such gain is less than<br />

the decrease in utility from such loss: the net utility from such chances is less than the<br />

utility <strong>of</strong> not taking such chances. See supra note 53.<br />

67. "Ceteris paribus" means "if all other relevant things (as fac<strong>to</strong>rs or elements)<br />

correspond or remain unaltered." WEBSTER'S THIRD NEW INTERNATIONAL DICTIONARY<br />

368 (1976).<br />

68. Increased variance (dispersion) increases the portion (tail) <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>ile (distribution)<br />

<strong>of</strong> chances <strong>of</strong> asset values above the call option's exercise price.<br />

69. "Capital-structure-unaffected market value" means that the corporation's<br />

market value is the sum <strong>of</strong> the market values <strong>of</strong> its bonds and s<strong>to</strong>cks unaffected by the<br />

market value ratio <strong>of</strong> its bonds <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>cks. See Smith, Jr., supra note 31, at 45. See generally<br />

Modigliani & Miller, The Cost <strong>of</strong> Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory <strong>of</strong><br />

Investment, 48 AM. ECON. REV. 261, 268 (1958) (stating that "the market value <strong>of</strong> any<br />

firm is independent <strong>of</strong> its capital structure"); Stiglitz, A Re-Examination <strong>of</strong> the Modigliani-Mioller<br />

Theorem, 59 AM. ECON. REV. 784, 788-89 (1969).<br />

70. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 56 & n.10, 58-60, 62-64, 71 & n.52 (discussing<br />

the conjoint use <strong>of</strong> the Black-Scholes option-pricing model and the intertemporal capital-asset-pricing<br />

model).<br />

71. Id. at 59-60, 63-64, 71 & n.53. For examples that the concept <strong>of</strong> decreasing<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholders' covariance risk by increasing the risk <strong>of</strong> corporate bankruptcy is apparently<br />

foreign <strong>to</strong> our commenta<strong>to</strong>rs, see Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 5, at 1442;<br />

McDaniel, <strong>Bondholders</strong> and Corporate Governance, 41 Bus. LAW. 413, 433-34 (1986).<br />

Diversifiable risk becomes economically irrelevant <strong>to</strong> risk-averse s<strong>to</strong>ckholders through<br />

their investment diversification in the efficient capital market.<br />

72. See supra notes 10, 23 and accompanying text.<br />

73. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 58-60, 63-64, 71 & n.53.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

investment project will be rejected in favor <strong>of</strong> a project <strong>with</strong> a higher<br />

variance <strong>of</strong>... returns. '74<br />

B. THE BONDHOLDER-WENBERGER HYPOTHETICAL<br />

1. Factual Aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

A "first-step acquisition" is the establishment <strong>of</strong> a less than complete<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck-ownership position in a corporation which becomes the<br />

basis for a subsequent attempt <strong>to</strong> increase that s<strong>to</strong>ck-ownership position;<br />

a "two-step acquisition" is the establishment <strong>of</strong> complete s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

ownership <strong>of</strong> a corporation by the integration through the second<br />

step <strong>of</strong> two individually less than complete s<strong>to</strong>ck-ownership positions.<br />

A "cash-out merger" is a merger in which the nonacquiring s<strong>to</strong>ckholders<br />

<strong>of</strong> the s<strong>to</strong>ck-acquired corporation receive money as the sole<br />

consideration for their s<strong>to</strong>ck and their elimination as s<strong>to</strong>ckholders.<br />

The "share price" is the amount <strong>of</strong> money for which a share <strong>of</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

is able <strong>to</strong> be bought or sold or is otherwise valued. The "premium<br />

over the market price" is the amount <strong>of</strong> money above the market<br />

price <strong>of</strong> a security that a buyer is willing <strong>to</strong> pay, or a seller is willing<br />

<strong>to</strong> accept, in exchange for that security. "Majority s<strong>to</strong>ckholder" status<br />

results when one corporation acquires more than fifty percent <strong>of</strong><br />

another corporation's s<strong>to</strong>ck: the s<strong>to</strong>ck-acquiring corporation becomes<br />

the "parent corporation" and the (partially or wholly) s<strong>to</strong>ck-acquired<br />

corporation becomes the "subsidiary corporation." A "dual parentsubsidiary<br />

direc<strong>to</strong>r" is an individual who is simultaneously a member<br />

<strong>of</strong> the board <strong>of</strong> direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> both the parent corporation and its subsidiary<br />

corporation.<br />

Weinberger represents the generalized fact pattern <strong>of</strong> a two-step<br />

acquisition in which the first-step acquisition and the second-step<br />

cash-out merger have equal share prices <strong>with</strong> approximately equal<br />

premiums over their market prices and in which majority s<strong>to</strong>ckholder<br />

and dual parent-subsidiary direc<strong>to</strong>r statuses result from the<br />

7 5<br />

first-step acquisition.<br />

The merger seems <strong>to</strong> have been nonsynergistic because both corporations<br />

were conglomerates (economically diversified) 76 and pure<br />

conglomerate mergers have no market value synergy. 77 At the time<br />

when the market price <strong>of</strong> the subsidiary's s<strong>to</strong>ck was $14.50 per<br />

74. Id. at 71. In other words, there is a chance that s<strong>to</strong>ckholders could "benefit<br />

from projects whose net effect ... [is] <strong>to</strong> reduce the <strong>to</strong>tal value <strong>of</strong> the firm." Jensen &<br />

Meckling, supra note 20, at 337 n.43.<br />

75. Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 704-08 (1983).<br />

76. Id. at 704.<br />

77. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 66 & n.38, 68.


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

share, 78 dual parent-subsidiary direc<strong>to</strong>rs had inside information "that<br />

it would be a good investment for [the parent] <strong>to</strong> acquire the remaining<br />

49.5% <strong>of</strong> [the subsidiary's] shares <strong>of</strong> any price up <strong>to</strong> $24 each." 79<br />

Because efficient market "theory is concerned <strong>with</strong> how the market<br />

reacts <strong>to</strong> disclosed information and is silent as <strong>to</strong> the optimum<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> information required or whether that optimum should be<br />

achieved on a manda<strong>to</strong>ry or voluntary basis," 8 0 this ($14.50 v. $24)<br />

share price discrepancy is consistent <strong>with</strong> the existence <strong>of</strong> an efficient<br />

capital market. The merger seems <strong>to</strong> have occurred in an efficient<br />

capital market because the s<strong>to</strong>cks <strong>of</strong> both corporations were publicly<br />

traded on the New York S<strong>to</strong>ck Exchange, 8 1 and this exchange is<br />

8 2<br />

more or less an efficient capital market.<br />

The parent corporation did not contemplate merging <strong>with</strong> the<br />

subsidiary corporation until almost three years after their s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

purchase bargaining in the first-step acquisition. 8 3 "No functional<br />

bright line can be drawn <strong>to</strong> <strong>of</strong>fer an easy operational distinction between<br />

a merger contemplated as a second step at the time control<br />

was acquired and a merger which was not so contemplated but is<br />

stimulated by events after the acquisition <strong>of</strong> control." '8 4 The positioning<br />

<strong>of</strong> unanticipated wealth expropriations might be a distinguishing<br />

financial feature between anticipated and unanticipated mergers.<br />

Unless the parent sells its s<strong>to</strong>cks in the subsidiary <strong>to</strong> the extent that<br />

its status as the majority s<strong>to</strong>ckholder is extinguished, the parent arguably<br />

is the only realistic purchaser for the aggregate <strong>of</strong> the subsidiary's<br />

minority s<strong>to</strong>cks. Second-step acquisition unanticipated wealth<br />

expropriations might occur because, at the time <strong>of</strong> the purchase <strong>of</strong><br />

the parent's or subsidiary's securities, the capital market: (1) perceives<br />

the parent as not completely acquiring the subsidiary's s<strong>to</strong>cks,<br />

(2) ambiguously perceives the parent as completely and not completely<br />

acquiring the subsidiary's s<strong>to</strong>cks, or (3) overreacts <strong>to</strong> the perception<br />

<strong>of</strong> the parent as completely acquiring the subsidiary's<br />

s<strong>to</strong>cks. 8 6 The approximate equality between the subsidiary's s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

78. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 706.<br />

79. Id. at 705.<br />

80. SEC. AND EXCH. COMM'N, REPORT OF THE ADVISORY COMM. ON CORP. DISCLO-<br />

SURE TO THE SEC. AND EXCH. COMM'N D-6 (1977).<br />

81. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 704.<br />

82. Fama & Blume, Filter Rules and S<strong>to</strong>ck-Market Trading, 39 J. Bus. 226 (1966).<br />

83. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 704-05.<br />

84. Brudney, supra note 2, at 1119 n.144.<br />

85. A. Barkey, supra note 1, at 16. Schedule 13D filings under section 13(d)(1) <strong>of</strong><br />

the Securities Exchange Act, 15 U.S.C. § 78m(d)(1) (1982) might not unambiguously<br />

signal information because <strong>of</strong> their boilerplate disclosure. Tobin & Maiwurm, Beachhead<br />

Acquisitions: Creating Waves in the Marketplace and Uncertainty in the Regula<strong>to</strong>r<br />

Framework, 38 Bus. LAW. 419, 434-36 (1983) (discussing waffling disclosure).<br />

86. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 70.<br />

8 5


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

market price <strong>of</strong> "a fraction under $14 per share" before the $21 per<br />

share first-step acquisition 8 7 and its s<strong>to</strong>ck market price <strong>of</strong> $14.50 per<br />

share before the $21 per share cash-out merger 8 8 is consistent <strong>with</strong><br />

the view that the capital market perceived the parent as not intending<br />

<strong>to</strong> completely acquire the subsidiary's s<strong>to</strong>cks because otherwise<br />

the share price before the $21 per share cash-out merger<br />

arguably would have been around $21 instead <strong>of</strong> $14.50. This apparent<br />

capital market perception is consistent <strong>with</strong> the fact that the parent<br />

did not contemplate merging <strong>with</strong> the subsidiary until almost<br />

three years after their s<strong>to</strong>ck purchase bargaining in the first-step<br />

acquisition. 89<br />

Thus, Weinberger represents the generalized fact pattern <strong>of</strong> a<br />

surprise nonsynergistic parent-subsidiary cash-out merger occurring<br />

in an efficient capital market. 90<br />

2. Dicta Aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

Weinberger involves a class action in equity, on behalf <strong>of</strong><br />

merger-objecting subsidiary s<strong>to</strong>ckholders who were eliminated as<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholders by operation <strong>of</strong> the merger statute, 91 challenging the<br />

fairness <strong>of</strong> the parent-subsidiary cash-out merger. 92 Although Weinberger's<br />

holding is irrelevant <strong>to</strong> the bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder focus <strong>of</strong><br />

this Article, 93 aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger's views are relevant. 94<br />

Weinberger states that "a more liberal approach [<strong>to</strong> securities<br />

valuation] must include pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> value by any techniques or methods<br />

which are generally considered acceptable in the financial community<br />

and otherwise admissible in court.1 95 Weinberger thereby opens<br />

the door <strong>to</strong> issues, detected by the Black-Scholes option-pricing<br />

framework, concerning unanticipated wealth expropriations among<br />

classes <strong>of</strong> corporate securities. 96 Weinberger: (1) affirms a fiduciary<br />

duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty (<strong>with</strong> "good management") on corporate <strong>of</strong>ficers and<br />

direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> the corporation, 97 (2) affirms a fiduciary duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty<br />

(<strong>with</strong> "complete candor") on corporate <strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> the<br />

87. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 704.<br />

88. Id. at 706.<br />

89. Id. at 704-05.<br />

90. See supra text accompanying notes 75-89.<br />

91. DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 251 (1974).<br />

92. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 703.<br />

93. For a statement <strong>of</strong> the narrow definition <strong>to</strong> be given <strong>to</strong> court determinations,<br />

see H. BLACK, HANDBOOK ON THE LAW OF JUDICIAL PRECEDENTS 37 (1912) and K.<br />

LLEWELLYN, THE BRAMBLE BUSH 42 (1960).<br />

94. For a statement <strong>of</strong> the persuasive authority <strong>of</strong> dicta, see K. LLEWELLYN, supra<br />

note 93, at 42.<br />

95. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 713.<br />

96. A. Barkey, supra note 1, at 6, 10.<br />

97. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 710.


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

corporation's s<strong>to</strong>ckholders, 9 8 (3) states that statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal "shall<br />

govern the financial remedy available <strong>to</strong> minority shareholders in a<br />

cash-out merger," 99 (4) finds that "there is a legislative intent <strong>to</strong> fully<br />

compensate shareholders for whatever their loss may be, subject only<br />

<strong>to</strong> the narrow limitation that one can not take speculative effects <strong>of</strong><br />

1 00 °<br />

the merger in<strong>to</strong> account, (5) states that "elements <strong>of</strong> future value,<br />

including the nature <strong>of</strong> the enterprise, which are known or susceptible<br />

<strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> as <strong>of</strong> the date <strong>of</strong> the merger and not the product <strong>of</strong> speculation,<br />

may be considered" in the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal, 1 01 (6) states<br />

that in the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal proceedings, "[w]hen the trial court<br />

deems it appropriate, fair value also includes any damages, resulting<br />

0 2<br />

from the taking, which the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders sustain as a class,"'<br />

(7) states that if the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal remedy is inadequate, then<br />

the courts may "fashion any form <strong>of</strong> equitable and monetary relief as<br />

'10 3<br />

may be appropriate, including rescissory damages.<br />

3. The Bondholder-Weinberger Hypothetical: Facts<br />

"Nonsubordinated bonds" are bonds having a corporate payment<br />

priority equal <strong>to</strong> that <strong>of</strong> other bonds while contractually established<br />

payment priorities operate among the corporation's bonds.' 0 4 The<br />

covariance between two returns equals the product <strong>of</strong> the positive<br />

square root <strong>of</strong> each return's variance times the "correlation coefficient."'<br />

0 5 The correlation coefficient can vary from +1 <strong>to</strong> 1: +1<br />

means perfect correlation, 0 means no correlation, and -1 means<br />

10 6<br />

perfect inverse correlation.<br />

Imagine two for-pr<strong>of</strong>it Delaware corporations--each having one<br />

98. Id. (quoting Lynch v. Vickers Energy Corp., 383 A.2d 278, 281 (Del. 1977)<br />

(quoting Lynch v. Vickers Energy Corp., 351 A.2d 570, 573 (Del. Ch. 1976))).<br />

99. Id. at 715 (construing DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 262(h) (1974)). See generally<br />

Seligman, Reappraising the Appraisal Remedy, 52 GEo. WASH. L. REV. 829, 831-37<br />

(1984); Thompson, Squeeze-Out Mergers and the "New" Appraisal Remedy, 62 WASH.<br />

U.L.Q. 415, 416-23 (1984).<br />

100. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 714.<br />

101. Id. at 713.<br />

102. Id. "Weinberger does not say when it would be appropriate <strong>to</strong> include this private<br />

eminent domain element <strong>of</strong> damages in the value determination.... Other than<br />

rescissory damages, it is difficult <strong>to</strong> imagine any damages that the court could have<br />

been contemplating." Berger & Allingham II, A New Light on Cash-Out Mergers:<br />

Weinberger Eclipses Singer, 39 Bus. LAW. 1, 18-19 (1983).<br />

103. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 714 (stating that courts may fashion such a remedy<br />

"particularly where fraud, misrepresentation, self-dealing, deliberate waste <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

assets, or gross and palpable overreaching are involved").<br />

104. See generally Everett, Subordinated Debt - Nature, Objectives and Enforcement,<br />

44 B.U.L. REV. 487, 489-96 (1964). For a theoretical discussion <strong>of</strong> debt subordination<br />

agreements, see Carlson, A Theory <strong>of</strong> Contractual Debt Subordination and Lien<br />

Priority, 38 VAND. L. REV. 975, 982-83 (1985).<br />

105. M. SPIEGEL, supra note 41, at 82.<br />

106. Id.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

class <strong>of</strong> publicly-traded s<strong>to</strong>cks and one class <strong>of</strong> risky publicly-traded<br />

pure-discount bonds <strong>with</strong> conjointly equal bond maturities-identical<br />

in every respect but for less than perfect correlation <strong>of</strong> returns between<br />

them. 0 7 The bond purchase prices and the bond protective<br />

contractual provisions do not anticipate a cash-out merger, the issuance<br />

<strong>of</strong> nonsubordinated bonds and the retirement <strong>of</strong> s<strong>to</strong>cks. 10 8 The<br />

capital market conforms <strong>to</strong> the Black-Scholes option-pricing framework<br />

and more or less <strong>to</strong> the intertemporal capital-asset pricing<br />

model. For each corporation, and for the combined corporation resulting<br />

from their merger, the corporate asset instantaneous covariance<br />

risk and capital-structure-unaffected market value are<br />

constant. 109<br />

One corporation obtains both dual parent-subsidiary direc<strong>to</strong>r and<br />

(50.5%) majority s<strong>to</strong>ckholder control <strong>of</strong> the other corporation. 1 10 The<br />

capital market perceives that these corporations will not undergo a<br />

cash-out merger <strong>with</strong> the issuance <strong>of</strong> nonsubordinated bonds and the<br />

retirement <strong>of</strong> s<strong>to</strong>cks. 1 ' These corporations undergo a surprise nonsynergistic<br />

cash-out merger three years later. 1 1 2 The cash-out share<br />

price equals the market price <strong>of</strong> the shares before the capital market<br />

was aware <strong>of</strong> the surprise cash-out merger proposal.' 1 3 Several days<br />

after the date <strong>of</strong> the merger, 1 1 4 the combined corporation makes the<br />

publicly announced decision 1 5 <strong>to</strong> issue a specified amount <strong>of</strong> nonsubordinated<br />

bonds, which will conjointly mature <strong>with</strong> the original<br />

bonds, and <strong>to</strong> use their proceeds for the merger cash-out, other specified<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck retirements, and maintaining a constant market value for<br />

the combined corporation." i 6 Also, the combined corporation<br />

publicly announces that it is instituting, through such bond issuance<br />

and s<strong>to</strong>ck retirements and through other means, a "prospective<br />

contingency plan" 117 <strong>of</strong> defense against corporate takeover so as "<strong>to</strong><br />

107. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 62.<br />

108. See Forsyth, Bad Grades, BARRON'S, Feb. 24, 1986, at 24, col. 1.<br />

109. See supra note 70 and accompanying text.<br />

110. See supra text accompanying note 75.<br />

111. See supra text accompanying notes 87-89.<br />

112. See supra text accompanying notes 76-77, 89-90.<br />

113. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 68.<br />

114. See supra text accompanying note 101.<br />

115. This emphasizes that the bond pricing <strong>of</strong> the new bonds will fully reflect (fairmarket-value<br />

impound) the new risks associated <strong>with</strong> the new facts. See E. FAMA &<br />

M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 78-79 n.31; Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 79 n.66. Cf.<br />

Prokesch, supra note 2, at D4, col. 6 (statement <strong>of</strong> Mr. Kingman D. Penniman, Vicepresident,<br />

McCarthy, Crisanti & Maffei) (stating, regarding Phillips Petroleum's restructuring:<br />

"Those holding the debt issued <strong>to</strong> finance the recapitalization have fared<br />

fairly because the interest paid reflects the new market risks.").<br />

116. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 63-69.<br />

117. Moran v. Household Int'l, Inc., 490 A.2d 1059, 1075 (Del. Ch.), affd, 500 A.2d<br />

1346 (Del. 1985).


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

protect the corporation from a perceived threat <strong>to</strong> corporate policy<br />

and effectiveness.' ' 1 8 The combined corporation fully complies <strong>with</strong><br />

all contractual obligations under all bond protective contractual<br />

provisions. 119<br />

Some <strong>of</strong> the subsidiary's s<strong>to</strong>ckholders dissent from the cash-out<br />

merger agreement and perfect their appraisal rights. 120 These s<strong>to</strong>ckholders<br />

and some <strong>of</strong> the original bondholders are risk-neutral and<br />

risk-liking inves<strong>to</strong>rs' 2 ' (during the time span <strong>of</strong> these events) 122 who<br />

possess unique investment facts and beliefs. 123 Arbitrarily, the net financial<br />

effect before the date <strong>of</strong> appraisal is, ceteris paribus, that<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholders gain wealth 124 and original bondholders lose corresponding<br />

wealth 25 because <strong>of</strong> unanticipated wealth expropriations in<br />

which: (1) s<strong>to</strong>ckholders lose wealth and original bondholders gain<br />

corresponding wealth due <strong>to</strong> the merger per se, 126 and (2) s<strong>to</strong>ckholders<br />

gain wealth and original bondholders lose corresponding wealth<br />

2 7<br />

due <strong>to</strong> the cash-outs per se.'<br />

A dispute over these gains and losses arises from the Delaware<br />

appraisal proceedings. Assume, representation by the original bondholders<br />

(Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs), the dissenting s<strong>to</strong>ckholders (Ap-<br />

118. Id. at 1076.<br />

119. See DEL. CODE ANN. tit. 8, § 259 (1974).<br />

120. See supra text accompanying note 99.<br />

121. This locally neutralizes a postulate <strong>of</strong> the intertemporal capital-asset-pricing<br />

model. See supra notes 56-57 and accompanying text.<br />

122. This emphasizes the problem that if rules <strong>of</strong> law were <strong>to</strong> distinguish between<br />

risk-averse and non-risk-averse inves<strong>to</strong>rs in favor <strong>of</strong> the latter, see Easterbrook & Fischel,<br />

Corporate Control Transactions, 91 YALE L.J. 698, 711-14 (1982), then a riskaverse<br />

inves<strong>to</strong>r - whose risk averseness is determined in court by testing that inves<strong>to</strong>r<br />

- can always allege, perhaps truthfully, that at a relevant past time the inves<strong>to</strong>r was<br />

risk-neutral or risk-liking. The fact <strong>of</strong> past inadequate risk diversification supports<br />

such an allegation even though the inves<strong>to</strong>r's true state <strong>of</strong> mind at that time is unknown.<br />

Furthermore, an inves<strong>to</strong>r might be inherently risk-averse, risk-neutral, and<br />

risk-liking because "[a] utility function need not be everywhere concave or everywhere<br />

convex." H. MARKOWITZ, supra note 52, at 218. E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9,<br />

at 203; Friedman & Savage, supra note 53.<br />

123. This locally neutralizes a postulate <strong>of</strong> the intertemporal capital-asset-pricing<br />

model. See supra note 58 and accompanying text.<br />

124. This mimics a synergistic merger <strong>with</strong> respect <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ckholders. See Brudney<br />

& Chirelstein, Fair Shares in Corporate Mergers and Takeovers, 88 HARV. L. REV. 297,<br />

308-09, 313-25 (1974).<br />

125. See Farrell, supra note 45, at 113 (stating that "for every s<strong>to</strong>ck owner who<br />

benefits from a s<strong>to</strong>ck buyback, acquisition, or leveraged buyout, there is a luckless<br />

holder <strong>of</strong> debt"); Weberman, Redmail, FORBES 173, 173 (Oct. 7, 1985) (stating: "In a lot<br />

<strong>of</strong> these big takeovers the acquired s<strong>to</strong>ckholders make a killing, but holders <strong>of</strong> the existing<br />

bonds take a hosing.").<br />

126. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 66, 68. This mimics a "negative"-synergistic<br />

merger <strong>with</strong> respect <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ckholders. See Lorne, A Reappraisal <strong>of</strong> Fair Shares in<br />

Controlled Mergers, 126 U. PA. L. REV. 956, 976 (1978).<br />

127. See Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 69.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 20<br />

praisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs), and the combined corporation (Deb<strong>to</strong>r). 128<br />

Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs seek compensation regarding the cash-outs per<br />

se loss. Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs seek compensation regarding the merger<br />

per se loss and the cash-outs per se gain. Deb<strong>to</strong>r seeks not <strong>to</strong> compensate<br />

Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs and Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs. The following<br />

selective arguments might be made:<br />

IV. A FIDUCIARY LAW SOLUTION<br />

A. THE BONDHOLDER-WEINBERGER HYPOTHETICAL: ARGUMENTS<br />

1. Deb<strong>to</strong>r Speaks Regarding Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

Our law is clear: 12 9 <strong>Bondholders</strong> (Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs) have<br />

no standing <strong>to</strong> maintain a claim for breach <strong>of</strong> fiduciary duty because<br />

bondholders are not equitable owners <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets and<br />

because corporate <strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs owe a fiduciary duty only <strong>to</strong><br />

those who are such equitable owners.' 30 "The s<strong>to</strong>ckholders <strong>of</strong> a corporation<br />

are the equitable owners <strong>of</strong> its assets .... ,,131<br />

"There is a generally accepted picture <strong>of</strong> corporate debt relationships<br />

under which the entire responsibility for governance falls <strong>to</strong><br />

the contract drafter."' 13 2 Thus, if a "fiduciary duty <strong>of</strong> good faith and<br />

fair dealing" <strong>to</strong> bondholders were <strong>to</strong> be imposed on the parent-suc-<br />

128. Because bondholder wealth is affected, the bondholders might be permitted <strong>to</strong><br />

speak either directly or indirectly or by parallel litigation. Bonds are deemed "shares<br />

<strong>of</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck" when the bonds can vote, etc., and such voting bondholders <strong>of</strong> the subsidiary<br />

might dissent from the cash-out merger agreement and seek appraisal. See DEL. CODE<br />

ANN. tit. 8, § 221 (1974). "Once a s<strong>to</strong>ckholder perfects his appraisal rights, he loses his<br />

status as a s<strong>to</strong>ckholder and becomes a credi<strong>to</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the corporation." Berger & Allingham<br />

II, supra note 102, at 21 (citing Braasch v. Goldschmidt, 41 Del. Ch. 519, -,<br />

199 A.2d 760, 766 (1964)).<br />

129. This case does not involve a claim <strong>of</strong> fraud, see Harff v. Kerkorian, 347 A.2d<br />

133, 133-34 (Del. 1975) (involving allegations <strong>of</strong> intentional looting <strong>of</strong> the corporation),<br />

or a claim <strong>of</strong> misconduct regarding bondholder equity conversion rights, see Pittsburgh<br />

Terminal Corp. v. Baltimore & Oh. R.R., 680 F.2d 933, 935 (3d Cir.), cert. denied, 459<br />

U.S. 1056 (1982); Van Gemert v. Boeing Co., 520 F.2d 1373, 1374-79 (2d Cir.), cert. denied,<br />

423 U.S. 947 (1975); Green v. Hamil<strong>to</strong>n Int'l Corp., 437 F. Supp. 723, 725-29<br />

(S.D.N.Y. 1977), or a corporation in bankruptcy, see Pepper v. Lit<strong>to</strong>n, 308 U.S. 295, 296-<br />

302 (1939). The view that "if expropriation is the game, fraud is its name," McDaniel,<br />

supra note 71, at 445, seems <strong>to</strong> be in error because it is <strong>to</strong>o broad, for example, "in an<br />

action at law for deceit or fraudulent misrepresentation an intent <strong>to</strong> defraud must be<br />

established." Harman v. Masoneilan Int'l, Inc., 442 A.2d 487, 499 (Del. 1982).<br />

130. Norte & Co. v. Manor Healthcare Corp., Nos. 6827, 6831, at 7-8 (Del. Ch. Nov.<br />

21, 1985) (available on LEXIS, States Library, Del file).<br />

131. State ex rel. Miller v. L<strong>of</strong>t, Inc., 156 A. 170, 172 (Del. Super. Ct. 1931). Cf. Revlon,<br />

Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forkes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 176 (Del. 1986) (stating<br />

that "while concern for various corporate constituencies is proper when addressing a<br />

takeover threat, that principle is limited by the requirement that there be some rationally<br />

related benefit accruing <strong>to</strong> the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders").<br />

132. Brat<strong>to</strong>n, Jr., The Interpretation <strong>of</strong> Contracts Governing Corporate Debt Relationships,<br />

5 CARDOZO L. REV. 371, 371 (1984) (discussing judicial intervention tension<br />

between liberal and strict contract interpretation).


1986] FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

cessor corporation in a parent-subsidiary cash-out merger because <strong>of</strong><br />

its control over both corporations agreeing <strong>to</strong> merge, then this fiduciary<br />

duty would be "discharged as a matter <strong>of</strong> law" when there is full<br />

corporate compliance <strong>with</strong> all obligations under all bond protective<br />

contractual provisions. 133 Because Deb<strong>to</strong>r has fully complied <strong>with</strong> all<br />

its obligations under all bond protective contractual provisions,<br />

such a fiduciary duty would be discharged if it were imposed.135<br />

Also, postmerger cash-outs (s<strong>to</strong>ck retirements) which are outside <strong>of</strong><br />

the merger agreement are not subject <strong>to</strong> such a fiduciary duty because<br />

they are outside <strong>of</strong> parent-successor control over both corporations<br />

agreeing <strong>to</strong> merge. 136 Because bondholders could have avoided<br />

adverse economic effects resulting from the cash-outs by investing in<br />

efficient market portfolios or in equal proportions <strong>of</strong> the corporation's<br />

bonds and s<strong>to</strong>cks, 137 they assumed the risks <strong>of</strong> their bonds by<br />

3 8<br />

choosing not <strong>to</strong> so invest.-<br />

133. Broad v. Rockwell Int'l Corp., 642 F.2d 929, 958 (5th Cir.), cert. denied, 454<br />

U.S. 965 (1981). Cf Gardner & Florence Call Cowles Found. v. Empire, Inc., 589 F.<br />

Supp. 669, 673 (S.D.N.Y. 1984) (stating: "<strong>Fiduciary</strong> duties in a debenture contract...<br />

do not exist in the abstract, but are derived from the Indenture itself."), vacated, 754<br />

F.2d 478 (2d Cir. 1985).<br />

134. See supra text accompanying note 119.<br />

135. See Broad v. Rockwell Int'l Corp., 642 F.2d 929, 958-59 (5th Cir.), cert. denied,<br />

454 U.S. 965 (1981).<br />

136. See id.<br />

137. See supra notes 51, 63 and accompanying text. Whether all inves<strong>to</strong>rs can own<br />

either efficient market portfolios or equal proportions <strong>of</strong> the corporation's affected<br />

classes <strong>of</strong> securities are questions <strong>of</strong> fact regarding the capital market. Compare Brudney,<br />

supra note 2, at 1099-1102 (stating that sufficient s<strong>to</strong>ck diversification is factually<br />

unlikely, etc.) <strong>with</strong> E. FAMA, supra note 28, at 253-54 (comparing substantial diversification<br />

benefits <strong>with</strong> randomly selected New York S<strong>to</strong>ck Exchange portfolio containing<br />

under sixteen different s<strong>to</strong>cks).<br />

138. This is a coercive risk-diversification policy: diversify in a special way or else<br />

suffer expropriations by the corporation(s) invested in. For portfolio arguments regarding<br />

equal treatment for inves<strong>to</strong>rs, compare Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 122,<br />

at 711-14 (presenting a s<strong>to</strong>ck diversification argument for "allowing the gains from corporate<br />

control transactions <strong>to</strong> be apportioned unequally" because "risk averse inves<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

can reduce the risk <strong>of</strong> losses <strong>with</strong>out extinguishing pr<strong>of</strong>itable-but-risky transactions")<br />

<strong>with</strong> DeMott, Current Issues in Tender Offer Regulation: Lessons From the British, 58<br />

N.Y.U.L. REV. 945, 983 n.191 (1983) (presenting a s<strong>to</strong>ck diversification argument that a<br />

"fund that mimics the composition <strong>of</strong> the market as a whole" might "not gain as <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

as it loses when corporate control is sold on terms that treat shareholders unequally")<br />

and McDaniel, supra note 71, at 436 (stating that "wealth transfers from bondholders<br />

<strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ckholders" involve risk that "cannot be eliminated by [bond] diversification") and<br />

id. (stating that "a mutual fund [<strong>of</strong> bonds and s<strong>to</strong>cks] is not a perfect substitute for a<br />

diversified portfolio"). For a review <strong>of</strong> the Easterbrook & Fischel gain-keeping s<strong>to</strong>ckdiversification<br />

argument, see Bebchuk, Toward Undis<strong>to</strong>rted Choice and Equal Treatment<br />

in Corporate Takeovers, 98 HARV. L. REV. 1693, 1784 (1985); C<strong>of</strong>fee, Jr., Regulating<br />

the Market for Corporate Control: A Critical Assessment <strong>of</strong> the Tender Offer's Role<br />

in Corporate Governance, 84 COLUM. L. REV. 1145, 1216-21 (1984). Another form <strong>of</strong> the<br />

assumption-<strong>of</strong>-risk view focuses on the partial anticipation <strong>of</strong> corporate events through<br />

the bond protective contractual provisions: bondholders are deemed <strong>to</strong> assume the entire<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> an uncertain future event when they show awareness <strong>of</strong> its possibility <strong>of</strong><br />

1 34


Regarding Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

Weinberger states that in the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal proceedings,<br />

"[w]hen the trial court deems it appropriate, fair value also includes<br />

any damages, resulting from the taking, which the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders sustain<br />

as a class."' 39 Because both Deb<strong>to</strong>r's and Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs'<br />

equity underwent a simultaneous merger per se loss <strong>of</strong> wealth,140<br />

Deb<strong>to</strong>r did not "take" this wealth from Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs. 141 Because<br />

Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs gained Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs' wealth from<br />

the merger per se loss, 142 Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs should look <strong>to</strong> Contractual<br />

Credi<strong>to</strong>rs for such merger per se loss compensation and not <strong>to</strong><br />

Deb<strong>to</strong>r.<br />

Weinberger states that "elements <strong>of</strong> future value, including the<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> the enterprise, which are known or susceptible <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> as<br />

<strong>of</strong> the date <strong>of</strong> the merger and not the product <strong>of</strong> speculation, may be<br />

considered" in the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal. 143 Because the cash-outs per<br />

se gain resulted from a financing decision made several days after the<br />

date <strong>of</strong> the merger 4 4 and therefore was not "known or susceptible <strong>of</strong><br />

pro<strong>of</strong> as <strong>of</strong> the date <strong>of</strong> the merger,"' 1 45 it should not be considered in<br />

the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal. Weinberger states that if the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal<br />

remedy is inadequate, then the courts may "fashion any form<br />

<strong>of</strong> equitable and monetary relief as may be appropriate, including rescissory<br />

damages."' 1 46 Because the cash-outs per se gain results from<br />

conditions under which the corporation has not gained wealth 147 and<br />

because Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs bear no investment risk 148 resulting<br />

from s<strong>to</strong>ck ownership under the increased corporate debt which is<br />

intertwined <strong>with</strong> such gain, 149 Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs should not share<br />

occurrence. See Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 182<br />

(Del. 1986) (stating: "The Notes covenants specifically contemplated a waiver <strong>to</strong> permit<br />

sale <strong>of</strong> the company at a fair price. The Notes were accepted by the holders on<br />

that basis, including the risk <strong>of</strong> an adverse market effect stemming from a waiver.").<br />

Should "fair price," or fair value, include unanticipated wealth expropriations?<br />

139. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 713.<br />

140. See supra note 126 and accompanying text.<br />

141. Cf. United States v. Willow River Power Co., 324 U.S. 499, 511 (1945) (holding<br />

that a mean-variance change in height <strong>of</strong> river was not a "taking" <strong>of</strong> property); Fama,<br />

Agency Problems and the Theory <strong>of</strong> the Firm, 88 J. POL. ECON. 288, 290 (1980) (discussing<br />

the "nexus <strong>of</strong> contracts perspective" in which "ownership <strong>of</strong> the firm is an irrelevant<br />

concept").<br />

142. See supra text accompanying note 126.<br />

143. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 713.<br />

144. See supra text accompanying notes 114-16, 127.<br />

145. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 713.<br />

146. Id. at 714.<br />

147. See supra text accompanying note 116.<br />

148. Cf. Lorne, supra note 126, at 987 (providing an argument against synergistic<br />

merger gain sharing).<br />

149. See supra text accompanying notes 116, 127.


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

in this net cash-outs per se gain.<br />

2. Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs Speak Regarding Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

Deb<strong>to</strong>r's argument regarding Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs is incorporated<br />

by reference 15 0 herein.<br />

Regarding Deb<strong>to</strong>r<br />

Weinberger finds that "there is legislative intent <strong>to</strong> fully compensate<br />

shareholders for whatever their loss may be, subject only <strong>to</strong><br />

the narrow limitation that one cannot take speculative effects <strong>of</strong> the<br />

merger in<strong>to</strong> account." 151 Because <strong>of</strong> this legislative intent, Deb<strong>to</strong>r<br />

should fully compensate appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs, <strong>with</strong>in or <strong>with</strong>out the<br />

1 5 2<br />

appraisal statute, for their nonspeculative merger per se loss.<br />

Weinberger states that "elements <strong>of</strong> future value, including the<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> the enterprise, which are known or susceptible <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> as<br />

<strong>of</strong> the date <strong>of</strong> the merger and not the product <strong>of</strong> speculation, may be<br />

considered" in the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal. 15 3 Although the cash-outs per<br />

se gain154 is not "known or susceptible <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> as <strong>of</strong> the date <strong>of</strong> the<br />

merger,"' ' 55 this gain is nonspeculative and known as <strong>of</strong> the date <strong>of</strong><br />

appraisal. 1 5 6 Weinberger states that if the statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal remedy<br />

is inadequate, then the courts may "fashion any form <strong>of</strong> equitable<br />

and monetary relief as may be appropriate, including rescissory damages.'1<br />

5 7 Because statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal does not adequately compensate<br />

Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs for the loss <strong>of</strong> their pro rata share <strong>of</strong> the present<br />

value as <strong>of</strong> the date <strong>of</strong> the merger <strong>of</strong> the nonspeculative gross cashouts<br />

per se gain which proceeds from the (synergistic) corporate debt<br />

capacity as <strong>of</strong> the instant <strong>of</strong> the merger, 58 Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs seek<br />

such compensation outside <strong>of</strong> statu<strong>to</strong>ry appraisal.<br />

3. Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs Speak<br />

It is basic that "our corporate law is not static. It must grow and<br />

develop in response <strong>to</strong>, indeed in anticipation <strong>of</strong>, evolving concepts<br />

and needs.' 5 9 Because the established theoretical structure <strong>of</strong> corpo-<br />

150. Incorporating supra notes 129-38 and accompanying text.<br />

151. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 714.<br />

152. For a statement <strong>of</strong> the merger per se loss, see supra text accompanying note<br />

126.<br />

153. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 713.<br />

154. For a statement <strong>of</strong> the cash-outs per se gain, see supra text accompanying<br />

note 127.<br />

155. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 713.<br />

156. See supra text accompanying notes 124, 127.<br />

157. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 714.<br />

158. See supra notes 38, 153-56 and accompanying text.<br />

159. Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., 493 A.2d 946, 957 (Del. 1985).


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

rate finance is grounded in science, our corporate law should be<br />

brought in<strong>to</strong> congruity <strong>with</strong> it by adoption in<strong>to</strong> our law <strong>of</strong> the implications<br />

<strong>of</strong> the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization<br />

and the Black-Scholes scientific conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation.<br />

A generic managerial fiduciary duty <strong>to</strong> bondholders proceeds<br />

from the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization:<br />

Weinberger affirms a fiduciary duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty (<strong>with</strong> "good management")<br />

on corporate <strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> the corporation; 160 in<br />

equivalent economic language, there is a generic managerial fiduciary<br />

duty <strong>to</strong> efficiently use corporate assets and maximize the current<br />

market value <strong>of</strong> the corporation. 161 Weinberger affirms a fiduciary<br />

duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty on corporate <strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> the corporation's<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholders; 162 in equivalent economic language, there is a generic<br />

managerial fiduciary duty <strong>to</strong> maximize the current market value <strong>of</strong><br />

the corporation's s<strong>to</strong>cks. 163 These generic managerial fiduciary duties<br />

logically proceed from the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value<br />

maximization: "optimal operating decisions for a firm at any point in<br />

time involve maximizing the market value <strong>of</strong> those securities outstanding<br />

before the operating decision is made."' 1 64 Because bondholders<br />

and s<strong>to</strong>ckholders are equal (interchangeable) securityholders<br />

under this rule,' 6 5 the generic managerial fiduciary duty <strong>to</strong> maximize<br />

the current market value <strong>of</strong> the corporation's s<strong>to</strong>cks implies that<br />

there is a corresponding generic managerial fiduciary duty <strong>to</strong> maximize<br />

the current market value <strong>of</strong> the corporation's bonds. When the<br />

anomaly in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization<br />

occurs and the generic managerial fiduciary duties <strong>to</strong> the corporation<br />

and its s<strong>to</strong>ckholders conflict, 166 then this generic managerial fiduciary<br />

duty <strong>to</strong> bondholders logically exists as the means <strong>to</strong> reconcile the<br />

conflict and res<strong>to</strong>re the rule by an implied bondholder-<strong>to</strong>-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder<br />

side payment. 167<br />

Translating the Black-Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation in<strong>to</strong><br />

the language <strong>of</strong> our corporate law, equitable ownership <strong>of</strong> the corporation's<br />

assets and cash flow corresponds <strong>to</strong> the seniority (priority) <strong>of</strong><br />

claims by classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders on those assets<br />

and cash flow. 68 Because, in general, bondholders and s<strong>to</strong>ckholders<br />

160. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 710. "A corporation has an interest <strong>of</strong> its own in being<br />

well managed." Gordon v. Elliman, 306 N.Y. 456, 466, 119 N.E.2d 331, 338 (1954).<br />

161. See supra notes 9, 17-18 and accompanying text.<br />

162. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 710.<br />

163. See supra notes 9, 17-18 and accompanying text.<br />

164. E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra note 9, at 176 (emphasis added).<br />

165. See supra notes 14-18 and accompanying text.<br />

166. See supra note 19 and accompanying text.<br />

167. See supra note 22 and accompanying text.<br />

168. See supra notes 31-37.


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

have first and residual claims respectively on the corporation's assets<br />

and cash flow, 169 they are correspondingly the first and residual equitable<br />

owners <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets and cash flow. Because corporate<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs owe fiduciary duties <strong>to</strong> the equitable<br />

owners <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets 1 70 and because, in general, bondholders<br />

are the first equitable owners <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets<br />

under the Black-Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation, 171 corporate<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs owe fiduciary duties <strong>to</strong> bondholders which correspond<br />

<strong>to</strong> those owed <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ckholders. Given the foundation <strong>of</strong> a<br />

bondholder-management fiduciary relation which proceeds from the<br />

rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization and the Black-<br />

Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation, the "fiduciary formula" permits<br />

compensation <strong>to</strong> bondholders (Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs) for their<br />

cash-outs per se loss: 172<br />

<strong>Fiduciary</strong> law creates causes <strong>of</strong> action for the entrus<strong>to</strong>r<br />

against the fiduciary, even if the parties did not contract.<br />

The courts can provide protection <strong>to</strong> the entrus<strong>to</strong>r by imposing<br />

on the fiduciary obligations that the parties would have<br />

agreed upon if the costs <strong>of</strong> contracting or the nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

relation had not precluded them from doing so. 173<br />

But for the nature <strong>of</strong> the bondholder-management fiduciary relation<br />

in which perfect ex ante foresight <strong>with</strong> perfectly specified bond pricing<br />

is not possible, 174 the bondholders and management would have<br />

agreed upon bond pricing which would obligate the corporation <strong>to</strong><br />

compensate the bondholders for wealth which otherwise and now is<br />

unanticipatedly expropriated from the bondholders because the efficient<br />

capital market would have impounded this expropriation in<strong>to</strong><br />

such bond pricing. 175<br />

169. V. BRUDNEY & M. CHIRELSTEIN, CASES AND MATERIALS ON CORPORATE FI-<br />

NANCE 79-81 (2d ed. 1979). "The claims <strong>of</strong> the various investment securities upon the<br />

earnings and assets <strong>of</strong> the enterprise are defined in the portion <strong>of</strong> the investment contract<br />

which sets forth the amount <strong>of</strong> such claims and prescribes their priority vis-a-vis<br />

other claimants." Id. at 79.<br />

170. See Norte & Co. v. Manor Healthcare Corp., Nos. 6827, 6831, at - (Del. Ch.<br />

Nov. 21, 1985) (available on LEXIS, States library, Del file).<br />

171. See supra notes 168-69 and accompanying text.<br />

172. For a statement <strong>of</strong> the cash-outs per se loss, see supra text accompanying note<br />

127.<br />

173. Frankel, <strong>Fiduciary</strong> Law, 71 CALIF. L. REV. 795, 825 (1983). The term "entrus<strong>to</strong>r"<br />

means "the party <strong>to</strong> whom the fiduciary owes fiduciary duties." Id. at 800 n.17.<br />

174. See supra notes 44-46 and accompanying text.<br />

175. See supra notes 28, 43 and accompanying text. Also, but for the nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

bondholder-management fiduciary relation in which bondholders have unequal bargaining<br />

power <strong>with</strong> management, see Brody, supra note 39, at 19, col. 1, and Farrell,<br />

supra note 45, at 114, the bondholders and management would have agreed upon expropriation<br />

countermeasures (e.g., bond buyback, bond renegotiation, bond substitution)<br />

which would obligate the corporation <strong>to</strong> compensate the bondholders for wealth<br />

which otherwise and now is unanticipatedly expropriated from the bondholders be-


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 20<br />

Such compensation <strong>to</strong> bondholders is the logical counterpart <strong>of</strong><br />

our corporate law's policy <strong>of</strong> permissive managerial resistance <strong>to</strong><br />

takeovers 176 because it <strong>of</strong>fsets the loss <strong>of</strong> the unrestricted capital<br />

market takeover mechanisms which rectifies the policy manifestation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the anomaly in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-Value maximization.<br />

177 Furthermore, such compensation is consistent <strong>with</strong> a<br />

public policy <strong>of</strong> competitive business maneuver: 178 if the bondholders<br />

and the corporation were <strong>to</strong> continuously recontract, then the alternatives<br />

would be for the bondholders <strong>to</strong> receive such net<br />

compensation through bond pricing in the efficient capital market 179<br />

or for bond protective contractual provisions which would "severely<br />

restrict the actions <strong>of</strong> the firm.' 8 0 The view that "[tjhe most obvious<br />

and important characteristic <strong>of</strong> long-term debt financing is that the<br />

holder ordinarily has not bargained for and does not expect any<br />

substantial gain in the value <strong>of</strong> the security <strong>to</strong> compensate for the<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> loss"'' 1 becomes irrelevant in this context because: (1) the<br />

components <strong>of</strong> bond pricing are functionally equivalent and impound<br />

the publicly known information regarding expected gain and risk<br />

cause management does so act or contract when the bondholders have more or less<br />

equal bargaining power <strong>with</strong> management. See Brody, supra note 39, at 19, col. 1; Farrell,<br />

supra note 45, at 114.<br />

176. For a statement <strong>of</strong> the policy <strong>of</strong> permissive managerial resistance <strong>to</strong> takeovers,<br />

see Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., 493 A.2d 946, 955 n.10 (Del. 1985); Moran v.<br />

Household Int'l, Inc., 500 A.2d 1346, 1350 (Del. 1985). See generally Veasey, Business<br />

Judgment Rule: The New Incarnation, Legal Times, March 10, 1986, at 25, col. 1.<br />

Deb<strong>to</strong>r has instituted takeover defenses which restrict a possible takeover by the bondholders<br />

or others. See supra text accompanying notes 117-18.<br />

177. See supra notes 21, 43-44 and accompanying text.<br />

178. In general, for-pr<strong>of</strong>it corporations compete <strong>with</strong> other for-pr<strong>of</strong>it corporations<br />

for business. The public policy supporting such competition is manifested in the federal<br />

antitrust laws.<br />

179. See supra notes 28, 43-44 and accompanying text.<br />

180. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27, at 55 n.5. See Jensen & Meckling, supra note<br />

20, at 338 (stating: "To completely protect the bondholders ... these [bond protective<br />

contractual] provisions would have <strong>to</strong> be incredibly detailed and cover most operating<br />

aspects <strong>of</strong> the enterprise including limitations on the riskiness <strong>of</strong> the projects undertaken.").<br />

Such restrictive contractual provisions are analogous <strong>to</strong> the imposition <strong>of</strong><br />

common law or statu<strong>to</strong>ry law rules." "[A]lthough the legal rules can protect against<br />

fraud and particularly blatant forms <strong>of</strong> self-dealing by management, they cannot do<br />

much more <strong>with</strong>out denying the company the benefits <strong>of</strong> management's expertise in<br />

making major corporate decisions." DeMott, supra note 138, at 1012 (summarizing the<br />

view <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional managerial prerogatives regarding mergers and tender <strong>of</strong>fers<br />

stated in Lip<strong>to</strong>n, Takeover Bids in the Target's Boardroom, 35 Bus. LAW. 101, 116-20<br />

(1979)). "[T]he design <strong>of</strong> specific legal rules governing the terms <strong>of</strong> mergers ... affecting<br />

managerial interests appears very costly if not impossible. In such areas, regulation<br />

cannot feasibly go beyond very general rules, such as the requirement <strong>of</strong> 'fairness,'<br />

<strong>with</strong>out creating severe obstacles <strong>to</strong> efficient managerial decision-making." Anderson,<br />

Conflicts <strong>of</strong> Interest: Ffficiency, Fairness and Corporate Structure, 25 UCLA L. REV.<br />

738, 790 (1978) (discussing statu<strong>to</strong>ry rules).<br />

181. AM. BAR FOUND., supra note 6, at 1.


1986] FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

through inves<strong>to</strong>r bargaining in the efficient capital market, 18 2 and<br />

(2) inves<strong>to</strong>rs in all investment vehicles expect appropriate gains from<br />

8 3<br />

their investments-<br />

Should risk-neutral and risk-liking inves<strong>to</strong>rs (such as Appraisal<br />

Credi<strong>to</strong>rs and Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs), 1 8 4 <strong>with</strong> or <strong>with</strong>out their possession<br />

<strong>of</strong> unique investment facts and beliefs, be penalized by permissive<br />

(judicially <strong>to</strong>lerated) wealth expropriations because <strong>of</strong> "the<br />

existence <strong>of</strong> diversification-not its employment"? 18 5 The question<br />

can be recast as follows: should inves<strong>to</strong>rs' risk-neutral and risk-liking<br />

states <strong>of</strong> mind be penalized? (The penalization <strong>of</strong> states <strong>of</strong> mind<br />

is the domain <strong>of</strong> the theory <strong>of</strong> criminal law.) 18 6 To penalize such inves<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

would be <strong>to</strong> punish mental nonconformity <strong>with</strong> procrustean<br />

idealized mathematical conditions regarding risk averseness and<br />

efficient market portfolios in an otherwise completely noncriminal<br />

context.187 Such penalization is perverse and unfair because these inves<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

are the victims and not the perpetra<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> such wealth expropriations.'<br />

88 Risk diversification does not rationally "exist" for<br />

risk-neutral and risk-liking inves<strong>to</strong>rs. Moreover, such penalization is<br />

contrary <strong>to</strong> a reasonable fiduciary "constraint that no inves<strong>to</strong>r be<br />

made worse <strong>of</strong>f by the transaction.' 8 9 "The requirement that<br />

everyone receive at least the value <strong>of</strong> his investment under existing<br />

conditions serves much the same function as the rule against<br />

182. See supra notes 28, 43-44, 59-60 and accompanying text.<br />

183. Risk-averse inves<strong>to</strong>rs seeks gains which are related <strong>to</strong> investment covariance<br />

risks, whereas risk-neutral inves<strong>to</strong>rs seek the greatest expected gains and risk-liking<br />

inves<strong>to</strong>rs seek the greatest possible gains. Risk-averse inves<strong>to</strong>rs dominate the marketclearing<br />

prices for securities in the efficient capital market; bond economic gains and<br />

losses are determined from such market-clearing prices.<br />

184. See supra text accompanying notes 121-22.<br />

185. Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 122, at 713.<br />

186. American civil law is directed <strong>to</strong>ward damages, whereas American criminal<br />

law is directed <strong>to</strong>ward states <strong>of</strong> mind. In general, an objective truth finder regarding<br />

an individual's state <strong>of</strong> mind would obviate the requirement for an "act" or "harm"<br />

under the theory <strong>of</strong> our criminal laws - pure thought crimes would exist - because<br />

the "act" and "harm" are not relevant per se but only as indica<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> the individual's<br />

forbidden state <strong>of</strong> mind. If the "act" were central <strong>to</strong> our criminal laws, then the "act"<br />

would be penalized <strong>with</strong>out the requirement for a concurrent forbidden state <strong>of</strong> mind.<br />

If "harm" were central <strong>to</strong> our criminal laws, then "insanity" would not be a defense<br />

because it does not undo the "harm"; and the crimes <strong>of</strong> "attempt," "conspiracy," and<br />

"solicitation" would not exist because there is no "harm" per se in these crimes. For a<br />

definition <strong>of</strong> these quoted terms and for a discussion <strong>of</strong> criminal law theory, see J.<br />

HALL, LAW, SOCIAL SCIENCE AND CRIMINAL THEORY (1982), and J. HALL, GENERAL<br />

PRINCIPLES OF CRIMINAL LAW (2d ed. 1960).<br />

187. See supra notes 54-58 and accompanying text.<br />

188. There exists a corporate financing policy under which unanticipated wealth<br />

expropriations either do not occur or are neutralized. Galai & Masulis, supra note 27,<br />

at 66 & n.37, 68-69; K. Shastri, supra note 26, at 55-57.<br />

189. Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 122, at 715.


theft." 190<br />

CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 20<br />

On these grounds and because "inequitable action does not become<br />

permissible simply because it is legally possible," 1 91 Contractual<br />

Credi<strong>to</strong>rs seek such compensation under a new fiduciary articulation<br />

which requires the corporation and its <strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong>:<br />

(1) maximize the present value <strong>of</strong> the returns, evaluated <strong>with</strong> respect<br />

<strong>to</strong> all eventualities, on corporate assets, and (2) make corporate side<br />

payments so all classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders receive<br />

more or less as much wealth as such classes would otherwise attain<br />

through alternative nonexpropriating corporate decisions. 192<br />

B. WHAT IS FAIR?<br />

Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs' argument applies Weinberger's general language<br />

<strong>to</strong> Deb<strong>to</strong>r and Deb<strong>to</strong>r's argument applies Weinberger's specific<br />

language <strong>to</strong> Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs. Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs' and Deb<strong>to</strong>r's<br />

argument applies existing law and a coercive risk-diversification policy<br />

<strong>to</strong> Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs. Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs' argument applies<br />

financial and fiduciary theory <strong>to</strong> Appraisal Credi<strong>to</strong>rs and<br />

Deb<strong>to</strong>r.<br />

What is fair? An advocate's answer <strong>to</strong> this question might be<br />

"Who is my client?" A scientist's answer <strong>to</strong> this question might be<br />

"What is the problem?" 1 93 Because fairness <strong>with</strong>in a system arguably<br />

means congruence <strong>with</strong> the postulates <strong>of</strong> that system and because<br />

190. Id.<br />

191. Schnell v. Chris-Craft Indus., 285 A.2d 437, 439 (Del. 1971).<br />

192. "As long as the <strong>to</strong>tal market value <strong>of</strong> the firm has increased... those who are<br />

better <strong>of</strong>f receive more than enough <strong>to</strong> compensate in turn those who are worse <strong>of</strong>f<br />

and so induce the latter <strong>to</strong> go along <strong>with</strong> the decision." E. FAMA & M. MILLER, supra<br />

note 9, at 71-72 n.4. Cf Myers, Determinants <strong>of</strong> Corporate Borrowing, 5 J. FIN. ECON.<br />

147, 158 (1977) (discussing renegotiation <strong>of</strong> the bond contracts). Part (1) forbids the<br />

corporate policies <strong>of</strong> inefficient use <strong>of</strong> corporate assets and waste <strong>of</strong> corporate assets;<br />

part (2) compels rectification <strong>of</strong> unanticipated wealth expropriations resulting from<br />

corporate decision making. Because a corporate policy <strong>of</strong> waste <strong>of</strong> corporate assets is<br />

grossly impermissible on public policy grounds, side payments would not be made<br />

under the alternative policy <strong>of</strong> preserving corporate assets. See generally supra notes<br />

22-23 and accompanying text. (An alternative corporate decision includes remaining<br />

<strong>with</strong> the status quo.) The new fiduciary articulation is operationally consistent <strong>with</strong><br />

the duty <strong>of</strong> the board <strong>of</strong> direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> seek "the maximization <strong>of</strong> the company's value at<br />

a sale for the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders' benefit," Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings,<br />

Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 182 (Del. 1986) (stating that direc<strong>to</strong>rs' duties <strong>of</strong> loyalty and care <strong>to</strong><br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholders were violated by asset-option lock-up and no-shop agreements which had<br />

as their principal object the protection <strong>of</strong> bondholders through interfering "<strong>with</strong> getting<br />

the best price for the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders at a sale <strong>of</strong> the company"), because it requires<br />

direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> maximize the value <strong>of</strong> corporate assets and <strong>to</strong> make corporate side payments<br />

so s<strong>to</strong>ckholders receive as much wealth as they would otherwise attain through<br />

alternative nonexpropriating corporate decisions.<br />

193. See T. KUHN, THE STRUCTURE OF SCIENTIFIC REVOLUTIONS 109-10, 148 (2d ed.<br />

1970) (stating the proposition that different paradigms perceive and solve different<br />

problems regarding common underlying facts).


1986] FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

only Contractual Credi<strong>to</strong>rs' argument is logically congruent <strong>with</strong> the<br />

applicable theoretical structure <strong>of</strong> corporate finance, Contractual<br />

Credi<strong>to</strong>rs state the fair position from the viewpoint <strong>of</strong> corporate finance.<br />

The new fiduciary articulation is fair <strong>to</strong> all classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's<br />

securityholders because it compels efficient use <strong>of</strong><br />

corporate assets <strong>with</strong> side payments so as <strong>to</strong> maximize gains and minimize<br />

losses for all such classes.<br />

The "transactions-costs view" 194 that a managerial fiduciary duty<br />

<strong>to</strong> bondholders should be created on the ground <strong>of</strong> the costs involved<br />

in contracting for bond protective contractual provisions and <strong>with</strong>out<br />

the foundation <strong>of</strong> a bondholder-management fiduciary relation' 95<br />

seems <strong>to</strong> be in error because: (1) the transactions costs aspect <strong>of</strong> the<br />

fiduciary formula cannot impose duties (obligations) <strong>with</strong>out the<br />

foundation <strong>of</strong> a fiduciary relation, 196 and (2) such transactions costs<br />

and their bond protective contractual provisions become irrelevant<br />

through bond pricing in the efficient capital market fully reflecting<br />

the extent <strong>to</strong> which bond protective contractual provisions are less<br />

than perfect or do not exist. 197 Furthermore, the transactions-cost<br />

view cannot solve the problem <strong>of</strong> the transformation <strong>of</strong> perfect ex<br />

ante contractual specificities in bond pricing in<strong>to</strong> imperfect ex post<br />

contractual specificities' 98 because: (1) a fully protected contract (in<br />

194. The transactions-costs view should not be confused <strong>with</strong> the costly-contracting<br />

hypothesis. The bond-pricing issue <strong>of</strong> inherent ex post unanticipated wealth expropriations,<br />

see supra text accompanying note 45; Smith, Jr. & Warner, supra note 39, at<br />

119 n.5, is separable from views "about whether the <strong>to</strong>tal value <strong>of</strong> the firm is influenced<br />

by the way in which the bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder conflict is controlled." Id. at<br />

119. The "costly contracting hypothesis" states "that control <strong>of</strong> the bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder<br />

conflict through financial contracting can increase the value <strong>of</strong> the firm," id at<br />

121, whereas the "irrelevance hypothesis" states that control <strong>of</strong> "the bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder<br />

conflict does not change the value <strong>of</strong> the firm." Id. at 120. The evidence supports<br />

the costly-contracting hypothesis. Id at 153. This means that economic fac<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

"are insufficient <strong>to</strong> induce the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders <strong>to</strong> maximize the value <strong>of</strong> the firm rather<br />

than maximizing the value <strong>of</strong> the equity." Id at 121. The factual dominance <strong>of</strong> the<br />

costly-contracting hypothesis is <strong>to</strong> be expected because the unrestricted capital market<br />

takeover mechanism, supra note 21 and accompanying text, supporting the irrelevance<br />

hypothesis when corporate investment policy is not fixed, see Smith, Jr. & Warner,<br />

supra note 39, at 120, is neutralized by our corporate law's policy <strong>of</strong> permissive managerial<br />

resistance <strong>to</strong> takeovers. See supra text accompanying notes 176-77.<br />

195. See McDaniel, supra note 71, at 447, 456.<br />

196. See supra note 173 and accompanying text. See also SEC v. Chenery Corp.,<br />

318 U.S. 80, 85-86 (1943) (stating that fiduciary status precedes content definition<br />

<strong>with</strong>in that status). Thus, notions about "efficient" or "optimal" fiduciary duties, Mc-<br />

Daniel, supra note 71, at 447 & nn.176-78, seem <strong>to</strong> have no meaning in the absence <strong>of</strong> a<br />

fiduciary relation which is the foundation for such fiduciary duties.<br />

197. See supra notes 28, 43-44 and accompanying text. Cf AM. BAR FOUND., supra<br />

note 6, at 13 (stating: "Of great importance, <strong>of</strong> course, is the relationship between the<br />

strength <strong>of</strong> the covenants and the other negotiated terms, including the interest<br />

rate.").<br />

198. See supra text accompanying note 45.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

which the extent <strong>of</strong> protection is determined by and correspondingly<br />

allocated <strong>to</strong> the specific risks anticipated) 199 is not a continuous process<br />

<strong>of</strong> recontracting, and (2) the transactions costs aspect <strong>of</strong> the fiduciary<br />

formula cannot admit <strong>of</strong> a continuous recontracting notion<br />

when the parties agree, or seek <strong>to</strong> agree, on fixed bond pricing. 200<br />

In the transactions-costs view, the fiduciary duty <strong>to</strong> bondholders<br />

is coterminous <strong>with</strong> the contractual obligation <strong>to</strong> bondholders 20 1 because<br />

a fiduciary duty created on the ground <strong>of</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> contracting<br />

is logically subsumed in<strong>to</strong> the fact <strong>of</strong> such contracting. In<br />

contrast, the new fiduciary articulation is not limited in its application<br />

by bond contractual obligations.<br />

V. THE NEW FIDUCIARY ARTICULATION<br />

A. GLOBAL WEALTH MAXIMIZATION<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

The generalized anomaly in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value<br />

maximization defines the new fiduciary articulation because<br />

it specifies what is <strong>to</strong> be rectified. Because this generalized<br />

anomaly applies generally <strong>to</strong> the corporation, 20 2 its new fiduciary articulation<br />

counterpart correspondingly applies generally <strong>to</strong> our corporate<br />

law. This new fiduciary articulation requires the corporation<br />

and its <strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong>: (1) maximize the present value <strong>of</strong><br />

the returns, evaluated <strong>with</strong> respect <strong>to</strong> all eventualities, on corporate<br />

assets, and (2) make corporate side payments so all classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's<br />

securityholders receive more or less as much wealth as<br />

such classes would otherwise attain through alternative nonexpropriating<br />

corporate decisions. 20 3 By its terms, the new fiduciary ar-<br />

20 4<br />

ticulation solves by external imposition the following problem:<br />

199. Cf. Posner, supra note 53, at 508 (1976) (indicating that overprotection <strong>of</strong> credi<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

is possible).<br />

200. See supra note 173 and accompanying text.<br />

201. See McDaniel, supra note 71, at 443, 447. Cf. Broad v. Rockwell Int'l Corp.,<br />

642 F.2d 929, 958-59 (5th Cir.), cert. denied, 454 U.S. 965 (1981). For a discussion <strong>of</strong> the<br />

view that Broad did not give due consideration <strong>to</strong> an unanticipated change in Iowa law<br />

(removing the prohibition on cash-out mergers) which affected the contractual rights<br />

and conversion value <strong>of</strong> the convertible subordinated debentures held by the original<br />

purchasers, see Recent Decisions, Trustee Under an Indenture, Issuing Corporation,<br />

and Successor Corporation Did Not Breach Indenture or <strong>Fiduciary</strong> Duties <strong>to</strong> Holders<br />

<strong>of</strong> Convertible Subordinated Debentures by Eliminating <strong>Bondholders</strong>' Conversion<br />

Rights Pursuant <strong>to</strong> A Merger-Broad v. Rockwell International Corp., 30 EMORY L.J.<br />

1167, 1168 n.3, 1200-02, 1205-09 (1981). Thus, Broad partially illustrates the unanticipated<br />

wealth expropriation problem discussed supra in the text accompanying notes<br />

43-46.<br />

202. See supra note 42 and accompanying text.<br />

203. For the limitation on corporate side payments while there is a significant<br />

chance <strong>of</strong> corporate bankruptcy, see supra note 192.<br />

204. The classical conception's, see supra text accompanying note 65, objection that<br />

it is necessary <strong>to</strong> maintain "the idea that agents (managers) are accountable <strong>to</strong> their


1986] FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ckholder use (or misuse) <strong>of</strong> production/investment<br />

policy frequently involves not some action, but the failure <strong>to</strong><br />

take a certain action (e.g., failure <strong>to</strong> accept a positive net<br />

present value project). Because <strong>of</strong> this, investment policy<br />

can be very expensive <strong>to</strong> moni<strong>to</strong>r, since ascertaining that the<br />

firm's production/investment policy does not maximise the<br />

firm's market value depends on magnitudes which are costly<br />

<strong>to</strong> observe. Solutions <strong>to</strong> this problem are not obvious. For<br />

example, if the indenture were <strong>to</strong> require the bondholders<br />

(rather than the s<strong>to</strong>ckholders) <strong>to</strong> establish the firm's investment<br />

policy, the problem would not be solved; the bondholders,<br />

acting in their self interest, would choose an investment<br />

policy which maximized the value <strong>of</strong> the bonds, not the<br />

20 5<br />

value <strong>of</strong> the firm.<br />

The new fiduciary articulation formalizes the evolutionary separation<br />

<strong>of</strong> corporate management from rank-and-file s<strong>to</strong>ckholder control.<br />

20 6 It benefits employees, communities, and national economic<br />

organization because it implicitly forbids corporate decisions which<br />

increase the risk <strong>of</strong> corporate bankruptcy <strong>with</strong>out correspondingly<br />

20 maximizing 7<br />

the present value <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets. In<br />

general, it inherently overrides bond protective contractual provisions<br />

because such provisions restrict the corporation's freedom <strong>to</strong><br />

principals (shareholders)," Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 2, at 1191, concededly<br />

does not apply <strong>to</strong> bondholders because managers are also their agents, see id. at 1195;<br />

and is otherwise overcome by: (a) the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization<br />

in which bondholders and s<strong>to</strong>ckholders are interchangeable <strong>with</strong> respect <strong>to</strong><br />

management, and (b) the Black-Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation in which bondholders<br />

are, in general, the first equitable owners <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets and cash<br />

flow. The objection regarding "prejudice (<strong>to</strong>] shareholders by decreasing the incentive<br />

<strong>of</strong> management <strong>to</strong> act in their best interest," id. at 1192, is overcome by the express<br />

requirements <strong>of</strong> the new fiduciary articulation. Additional objections regarding unknowable<br />

future decisions by possible takeover successors, how <strong>to</strong> balance possible<br />

gains and losses, etc., see id. at 1190-91, are likewise overcome by the express requirements<br />

<strong>of</strong> the new fiduciary articulation.<br />

205. Smith, Jr. & Warner, supra note 39, at 130 (footnote omitted). Accord W.<br />

KLEIN, supra note 20, at 190 (stating, <strong>with</strong> respect <strong>to</strong> bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder, common<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholder - preferred s<strong>to</strong>ckholder and option/warrantholder - s<strong>to</strong>ckholder corporate<br />

conflicts <strong>of</strong> interest: "There appears <strong>to</strong> be no fully satisfac<strong>to</strong>ry solution <strong>to</strong> the<br />

problem that may be created by this kind <strong>of</strong> prospective conflict .... [I]t appears <strong>to</strong><br />

have received little analytic attention.").<br />

206. See A.A. BARLE & G.C. MEANS, THE MODERN CORPORATION AND PRIVATE<br />

PROPERTY 119-125, 356-57 (1932); Fama, supra note 141, at 290; Jensen & Meckling,<br />

supra note 20, at 343-51, 353. For a review <strong>of</strong> schools-<strong>of</strong>-thought (models) regarding<br />

corporate governance, see Mangrum, In Search <strong>of</strong> a Paradigm <strong>of</strong> Corporate Social Responsibility,<br />

17 CREIGHTON L. REV. 21, 26-49 (1983). The "public interest" model's concern<br />

about the separation <strong>of</strong> corporate ownership and control, see id. at 33 is<br />

theoretically overcome by a "scientific" model (the new fiduciary articulation) which<br />

integrates financial theory <strong>with</strong> the "contract" and "rights" models <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

governance.<br />

207. See supra notes 71, 73-74 & 192 and accompanying text.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

maximize returns on corporate assets 208 in competitive business maneuver:<br />

209 the continuing managerial fiduciary duties under the new<br />

fiduciary articulation cannot be contracted away by the parties because<br />

they are superimposed on public policy grounds. 210 The new fiduciary<br />

articulation requires immunization (e.g., by book-entry<br />

changes in bond redemption value) <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securities<br />

from unanticipated wealth expropriations resulting from corporate<br />

decisions, but it does not require immunization from all unanticipated<br />

changes in risk or value because it speaks solely <strong>to</strong> corporate<br />

decision making.<br />

The new fiduciary articulation is the economic functional<br />

equivalent <strong>of</strong> the bundle (vec<strong>to</strong>r) <strong>of</strong> possible corporate fiduciary duties<br />

because the essential concern for all inves<strong>to</strong>rs in the for-pr<strong>of</strong>it<br />

corporation is wealth maximization. Conflicting ideals create elaborate<br />

systems <strong>of</strong> learning which disappear when these conflicts are resolved:<br />

21 ' "[T]he rules that govern the managers' duty <strong>of</strong> care have<br />

been distinguished from the rules governing the duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty....<br />

The duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty and the duty <strong>of</strong> care ... are treated differently,<br />

<strong>with</strong> the business judgment rule covering only the latter. '212 With<br />

respect <strong>to</strong> the integrated managerial activity <strong>of</strong> decision making, 21 3 it<br />

is a conflict <strong>of</strong> ideals <strong>to</strong>: (1) have a judicial hands-<strong>of</strong>f policy <strong>of</strong> supporting<br />

managerial prerogatives through an operationally advisory fiduciary<br />

duty (duty <strong>of</strong> care <strong>with</strong> the business judgment rule), 214<br />

(2) have a judicial hands-on policy <strong>of</strong> supporting rectification <strong>of</strong> inves<strong>to</strong>r<br />

grievances through an operationally compulsory fiduciary duty<br />

(duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty <strong>with</strong> the entire-fairness careful-scrutiny rule), 215<br />

208. See supra note 180 and accompanying text.<br />

209. See supra note 178 and accompanying text.<br />

210. Bond contractual provisions regarding corporate payment priorities do not restrict<br />

corporate operations and thus would not be overridden by the new fiduciary<br />

articulation.<br />

211. T. ARNOLD, THE FOLKLORE OF CAPITALISM 364-65 (1937).<br />

212. Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 2, at 1197. For a statement <strong>of</strong> the Delaware<br />

business judgment rule, see Aronson v. Lewis, 473 A.2d 805, 812 (Del. 1984). For<br />

a discussion <strong>of</strong> duty <strong>of</strong> care and duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty issues, see Hinsey, Business Judgment<br />

and the American Law Institute's Corporate Governance Project: The Rule, the Doctrine,<br />

and the Reality, 52 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 609 (1984); Manning, The Business Judgment<br />

Rule and the Direc<strong>to</strong>r's <strong>Duty</strong> <strong>of</strong> Attention: Time for Reality, 39 BUS. LAW. 1477,<br />

1492-97 (1984); Ruder, <strong>Duty</strong> <strong>of</strong> Loyalty - A Law Pr<strong>of</strong>essor's Status Report, 40 BuS.<br />

LAW. 1383 (1985); Veasey, Further Reflections on Court Review <strong>of</strong> Judgments <strong>of</strong> Direc<strong>to</strong>rs:<br />

Is the Judicial Process Under Control?, 40 Bus. LAW. 1373 (1985). See also RE-<br />

STATEMENT (SECOND) OF AGENCY §§ 379, 387 (1957); RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF<br />

TRUSTS §§ 170, 174 (1957).<br />

213. See C. BARNARD, THE FUNCTIONS OF THE EXECUTIVE 185-211 (13th ed. 1968).<br />

214. See Johnson v. Trueblood, 629 F.2d 287, 292 (3d Cir. 1980). See generally Unocal<br />

Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., 493 A.2d 946, 954 (Del. 1985).<br />

215. See Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 710. For a statement <strong>of</strong> the entire-fairness careful-scrutiny<br />

rule, see infra text accompanying note 240.


1986] FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

(3) allocate the burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> under the operationally compulsory<br />

fiduciary duty so as <strong>to</strong> reconstitute the operationally advisory fiduciary<br />

duty, 2 16 and (4) sometimes allocate the burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> under the<br />

operationally advisory fiduciary duty in a manner which resembles<br />

such allocation under the operationally compulsory fiduciary duty. 217<br />

An underlying theoretical reason for the conjointment <strong>of</strong> such conflicting<br />

ideals seems <strong>to</strong> be that our adversarial procedural structure<br />

- in which issue resolution occurs through dialectical alternation<br />

under a neutral (nondirected or passive) adjudica<strong>to</strong>r - is partially inappropriate<br />

for the adjudication <strong>of</strong> problems in which there is an in-<br />

2 18<br />

tertwining <strong>of</strong> issues.<br />

By its terms, the new fiduciary articulation points <strong>to</strong>:<br />

(a) derivative claims for its part (1) breach because the corporation is<br />

the legal owner <strong>of</strong> its assets, and (b) individual claims for its part<br />

(2) breach because side payments are an inherent incident <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

security ownership under it. 219 Because there cannot be a basis<br />

for a derivative claim <strong>with</strong>out a corresponding individual claim for<br />

side payment by some securityholder and because there can be a<br />

216. See infra text accompanying notes 247-49.<br />

217. See Unocal Corp., 493 A.2d at 954-58 (discussing and enhanced duty <strong>of</strong> care<br />

<strong>with</strong> the business judgment rule based, in part, on duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty consideration, stated<br />

in Guth v. L<strong>of</strong>t, Inc., 5 A.2d 503, 510 (Del. 1939)). "While the business judgment rule<br />

may be applicable <strong>to</strong> the actions <strong>of</strong> corporate direc<strong>to</strong>rs responding <strong>to</strong> takeover threats,<br />

the principles upon which it is founded - care, loyalty and independence - must first<br />

be satisfied." Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 180<br />

(Del. 1986) (footnote omitted).<br />

218. See Fuller, Adjudication and the Rule <strong>of</strong> Law, 1960 PROC. AM. SOC'Y INT'L L.<br />

1, 3-5 (discussing polycentric problems). For other considerations, compare Moran v.<br />

Household Int'l, Inc., 490 A.2d 1059, 1074 (Del. Ch.) (stating that "[b]ecause the role <strong>of</strong><br />

a fiduciary ordinarily does not admit <strong>of</strong> any conflicting interests or conduct the business<br />

judgment rule seeks <strong>to</strong> accommodate that status <strong>to</strong> the realities <strong>of</strong> the business<br />

world."), affd, 500 A.2d 1346 (Del. 1985) <strong>with</strong> Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 2, at<br />

1199 (stating that the rationales underlying the business judgment rule are "the inability<br />

<strong>of</strong> courts <strong>to</strong> make better business decisions than managers" and "the inefficiency<br />

that would result were managers encouraged <strong>to</strong> disregard the costs <strong>of</strong> gathering information<br />

and making decisions"). Given our adversarial procedural structure, the dicho<strong>to</strong>my<br />

between monocentric (justiciable) and polycentric (nonjusticiable) problems<br />

is a ground under the new fiduciary articulation for the use <strong>of</strong> a generic business judgment<br />

rule and <strong>of</strong> a generic entire-fairness careful-scrutiny rule: in general, business<br />

problems essentially are polycentric (this would be the presumption <strong>of</strong> a business judgment<br />

rule) except for possible conflicts between fiduciary duties, etc., which essentially<br />

are monocentric (this would be the presumption <strong>of</strong> an entire-fairness careful-scrutiny<br />

rule).<br />

219. Cf. Abelow v. Symonds, 38 Del. Ch. 572, 578, 156 A.2d 416, 420 (1959) (stating<br />

that individual claims are "designed <strong>to</strong> enforce common rights running against plaintiffs'<br />

own corporation or those dominating it, while" derivative claims are designed<br />

"for the purpose <strong>of</strong> remedying wrongs <strong>to</strong> the corporation itself"). For a discussion <strong>of</strong><br />

the characterization <strong>of</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ckholder claims as derivative or individual, see Welch,<br />

Shareholder Individual and Derivative Actions: Underlying Rationales and the<br />

Closely Held Corporation, 9 J. CORP. L. 147, 148 & nn.1-3, 149-69 (1984).


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 20<br />

basis for an individual claim for side payment <strong>with</strong>out a corresponding<br />

derivative claim by some securityholder, 220 the individual claim<br />

overrides the derivative claim. 22 1 For example, there cannot be a derivative<br />

claim regarding a nonsynergistic merger per se because the<br />

corporation's assets (market value) are not damaged, but there can be<br />

an individual claim for side payment regarding an unanticipated<br />

wealth expropriation in such a merger. 222 What do such individual<br />

claims mean for corporate governance? The answer <strong>to</strong> this question<br />

is <strong>to</strong> be found in the logical extension <strong>of</strong> Weinberger's views.<br />

B. PROCEDURAL FAIRNESS<br />

1. Additional Factual Aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger<br />

Four dual parent-subsidiary direc<strong>to</strong>rs - in differing internal<br />

combinations - requested, performed, and discussed a feasibility<br />

study on the parent's acquiring the subsidiary's remaining publicly<br />

held shares. 223 This feasibility study used the subsidiary's "information<br />

for the exclusive benefit <strong>of</strong>" the parent 224 and concluded "that it<br />

would be a good investment for [the parent] <strong>to</strong> acquire the remaining<br />

49.5% <strong>of</strong> [the subsidiary's] shares at any price up <strong>to</strong> $24 each." 225 The<br />

subsidiary's president, a dual parent-subsidiary direc<strong>to</strong>r who participated<br />

in the parent's executive committee meeting which<br />

220. Also, a securityholder might recast a derivative claim in<strong>to</strong> an individual claim<br />

for side payment if there is a procedural advantage (e.g., application <strong>of</strong> an entire-fairness<br />

careful-scrutiny rule instead <strong>of</strong> a business judgment rule) in doing so.<br />

221. See generally Brat<strong>to</strong>n, Jr., The Economics and Jurisprudence <strong>of</strong> Convertible<br />

Bonds, 1984 WIs. L. REV. 667, 733-39; Clark, The Duties <strong>of</strong> the Corporate Deb<strong>to</strong>r <strong>to</strong> its<br />

Credi<strong>to</strong>rs, 90 HARV. L. REV. 505 (1977); C<strong>of</strong>fee, Jr. & Schwartz, The Survival <strong>of</strong> the Derivative<br />

Suit: An Evaluation and a Proposal for Legislative Reform, 81 COLUM. L.<br />

REV. 261, 262 (1981); Levmore, Moni<strong>to</strong>rs and Freeriders in Commercial and Corporate<br />

Settings, 92 YALE L.J. 49, 80-82 (1982); Note, Credi<strong>to</strong>rs' Derivative Suits on Behalf <strong>of</strong><br />

Solvent Corporations, 88 YALE L.J. 1299 (1979); Note, Public Credi<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> <strong>Financial</strong> Institutions:<br />

The Case for a Derivative Right <strong>of</strong> Action, 86 YALE L.J. 1422, 1446-47 (1977).<br />

The argument that the economic case for bondholder derivative suits is compelling because<br />

their misconduct-deterrence effect leads <strong>to</strong> a reduction in the cost <strong>of</strong> debt capital,<br />

McDaniel, supra note 71, at 452 & nn.214-16, seems <strong>to</strong> be irrelevant from the viewpoint<br />

<strong>of</strong> the corporation's bondholders because the corporation's securityholders are indifferent<br />

about its financing decisions <strong>with</strong>in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value<br />

maximization. See supra note 17 and accompanying text. In general, the separability<br />

<strong>of</strong> corporate financing and operating decisions occurs when there is no optimal capital<br />

structure for the corporation, see Miller, Debt and Taxes, 32 J. FIN. 261, - (1977), or<br />

when an optimal capital structure is not changed by the corporation, see DeAngelo &<br />

Masulis, Optimal Capital Structure Under Corporate and Personal Taxation, 8 J. FIN.<br />

ECON. 3 (1980).<br />

222. See supra note 48 and accompanying text.<br />

223. Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 705. There were seven parent designee direc<strong>to</strong>rs (six<br />

dual parent-subsidiary direc<strong>to</strong>rs) on the subsidiary's thirteen member board <strong>of</strong> direc<strong>to</strong>rs.<br />

Id. at 704-05.<br />

224. Id. at 709.<br />

225. Id. at 705.


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

responsively authorized its management <strong>to</strong> arrange for a subsidiary<br />

cash-out merger <strong>with</strong>in the price range <strong>of</strong> $20 <strong>to</strong> $21 per share and <strong>to</strong><br />

present a merger proposal <strong>to</strong> the parent's board <strong>of</strong> direc<strong>to</strong>rs four<br />

business days later, 226 retained an investment banking firm <strong>to</strong> pro-<br />

2 27<br />

vide a fairness opinion on the prospective cash-out merger <strong>of</strong>fer.<br />

He did not at any time seek a cash-out share price higher than $21<br />

per subsidiary share; 228 there was no parent-subsidiary bargaining<br />

2 29<br />

over the cash-out share price.<br />

The parent and subsidiary boards <strong>of</strong> direc<strong>to</strong>rs met - separately,<br />

but <strong>with</strong> telephone contact maintained between the meetings - <strong>to</strong><br />

consider the cash-out merger proposal. 230 The parent formally proposed<br />

<strong>to</strong> the subsidiary a $21 per share cash-out merger agreement<br />

requiring that the minimum number <strong>of</strong> the subsidiary's majority <strong>of</strong><br />

the minority shares voting for the merger equal about two-thirds <strong>of</strong><br />

all the subsidiary's minority shares. 231 The subsidiary's investment<br />

banking opinion letter, which was hurriedly prepared during the four<br />

business day span, found the $21 share price <strong>to</strong> be fair. 232 Although<br />

the parent's feasibility study <strong>with</strong> its $24 subsidiary share price valuation<br />

"was made available <strong>to</strong>" dual parent-subsidiary direc<strong>to</strong>rs, 233 it<br />

was not discussed at the subsidiary's board meeting 234 nor shared<br />

<strong>with</strong> the subsidiary's nonparent designee direc<strong>to</strong>rs. 235 The subsidiary's<br />

board <strong>of</strong> direc<strong>to</strong>rs, <strong>with</strong> the active nonvoting participation and<br />

support <strong>of</strong> its parent designee direc<strong>to</strong>rs, adopted a resolution <strong>to</strong> accept<br />

the parent's $21 per share cash-out merger <strong>of</strong>fer. 236<br />

The cash-out merger agreement was approved by a majority vote<br />

<strong>of</strong> the subsidiary's minority shares at the subsidiary's annual meeting<br />

fifty-nine business days later. 237 The subsidiary's proxy statement regarding<br />

this cash-out merger agreement vote did not disclose:<br />

(1) "the circumstances surrounding the rather cursory preparation <strong>of</strong><br />

the [investment banking] fairness opinion" while "the impression was<br />

given [the subsidiary's] minority that a careful study had been<br />

made, '23 8 and (2) "the critical information that [the parent]<br />

226. Id. at 705-06.<br />

227. Id. at 706.<br />

228. Id. at 706, 711.<br />

229. Id. at 711.<br />

230. Id. at 707.<br />

231. Id.<br />

232. Id.<br />

233. Id at 709.<br />

234. Id. at 707.<br />

235. Id. at 708.<br />

236. Id. at 707.<br />

237. Id. at 708 (stating the percentage as "51.9% <strong>of</strong> the <strong>to</strong>tal minority").<br />

238. Id. at 712.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

considered a price <strong>of</strong> $24 <strong>to</strong> be a good investment. '239<br />

2. Additional Dicta Aspects <strong>of</strong> Weinberger<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

Weinberger states that "where one stands on both sides <strong>of</strong> a<br />

transaction, he has the burden <strong>of</strong> establishing its entire fairness, sufficient<br />

<strong>to</strong> pass the test <strong>of</strong> careful scrutiny by the courts. '240 Weinberger<br />

views procedural-fairness standards as testing for arm's-length<br />

bargaining in an otherwise self-dealing transaction: 24 1 Procedural<br />

fairness at the subsidiary's negotiating level includes the dual parentsubsidiary<br />

direc<strong>to</strong>rs' absolute noninvolvement in the transaction or<br />

an independent negotiating committee <strong>of</strong> outside direc<strong>to</strong>rs bargaining<br />

<strong>with</strong> the parent at arm's length. 242 Procedural fairness at the subsidiary's<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholder level includes neutralized voting, whereby a majority<br />

<strong>of</strong> the subsidiary's minority shares can approve or disapprove the<br />

merger, 243 based on complete disclosure <strong>of</strong> "all material facts relevant<br />

<strong>to</strong> the transaction" by "those relying on the vote. '244 Because<br />

an informed vote <strong>of</strong> the majority <strong>of</strong> the subsidiary's minority shares<br />

approving the merger will shift the burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> back <strong>to</strong> the<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ckholder "plaintiff attacking the merger, '245 and because an independent<br />

negotiating committee <strong>of</strong> the subsidiary's outside direc<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

is "strong evidence" <strong>of</strong> fairness, 2 46 these independent means <strong>of</strong> procedural<br />

fairness are strongly mutually reinforcing.<br />

The entire-fairness careful-scrutiny rule logically (by its terms)<br />

does not apply while adequate procedural fairness exists because<br />

there is no possible conflict <strong>of</strong> fiduciary duties. 247 Hence, "an acquisition<br />

<strong>with</strong> these procedural protections would be reviewed by the<br />

courts under a standard resembling the 'business judgment' rule applicable<br />

<strong>to</strong> an acquisition by an unrelated third party. '248 In other<br />

words, the allocation <strong>of</strong> the burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> under an entire-fairness<br />

careful-scrutiny standard <strong>of</strong> judicial review reconstitutes a business<br />

239. Id.<br />

240. Id. at 710. "There is no 'safe harbor' for such divided loyalties in Delaware."<br />

Id. For Weinberger's definition <strong>of</strong> "entire fairness" in the cash-out merger context,<br />

see id. at 711. Cf. Revlon, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 182 (stating that "the... board could not<br />

make the requisite showing <strong>of</strong> good faith by preferrint the noteholders and ignoring its<br />

duty <strong>of</strong> loyalty <strong>to</strong> the shareholders").<br />

241. See Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 703, 709-11.<br />

242. Id. at 710-11.<br />

243. Id. at 703, 707.<br />

244. Id. at 703.<br />

245. Id.<br />

246. Id. at 709-10 n.7.<br />

247. See supra text accompanying note 240.<br />

248. Chazen, Fairness from a <strong>Financial</strong> Point <strong>of</strong> View in Acquisitions <strong>of</strong> Public<br />

Companies: Is "Third-Party Sale Value" the Appropriate Standard?, 36 Bus. LAW.<br />

1439, 1441 (1981) (footnote omitted).


1986]<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

judgment rule through procedural fairness standards. 249<br />

Thus, Weinberger represents the generalized view that a corporate<br />

decision requires an entire-fairness careful-scrutiny standard <strong>of</strong><br />

judicial review, which reconstitutes a business judgment rule through<br />

procedural-fairness standards, when there is a possible conflict <strong>of</strong> fiduciary<br />

duties on the corporate decision maker regarding that<br />

decision. 250<br />

3. The Procedural-Fairness Structure<br />

The foundation <strong>of</strong> a securityholder-management fiduciary relation<br />

proceeds from the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value max-<br />

25 1<br />

imization and the Black-Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation.<br />

The possible conflict <strong>of</strong> fiduciary duties on management <strong>to</strong> the classes<br />

<strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders proceeds from the generalized<br />

anomaly in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization.<br />

252 This possible conflict is reconciled and the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

current-market-value maximization is res<strong>to</strong>red by the new fiduciary<br />

articulation which neutralizes such generalized anomaly. 25 3 An individual<br />

claim for side payment ipso fac<strong>to</strong> alleges management's breach<br />

<strong>of</strong> the new fiduciary articulation and the operation <strong>of</strong> such generalized<br />

anomaly <strong>with</strong> its consequent possible conflict <strong>of</strong> fiduciary duties.<br />

Because <strong>of</strong> this possible conflict <strong>of</strong> fiduciary duties, an entire-fairness<br />

careful-scrutiny rule <strong>with</strong> its procedural-fairness reconstituted business<br />

judgment rule logically applies <strong>to</strong> judicial review <strong>of</strong> individual<br />

claims for side payments. 25 4<br />

Thus, an entire-fairness careful-scrutiny rule overrides a business<br />

judgment rule in judicial review <strong>of</strong> individual claims. If there<br />

exists only one de fac<strong>to</strong> class <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders, 255<br />

249. See supra text accompanying notes 245-48.<br />

250. See supra text accompanying notes 240-01, 245-49.<br />

251. See supra notes 160-71 and accompanying text.<br />

252. See supra note 42 and accompanying text.<br />

253. See supra notes 19, 22-23, 42, & 192 and accompanying text.<br />

254. See supra notes 218, 250 and accompanying text. In other words, an entirefairness<br />

care-scrutiny rule applies because management stands on both fiduciary sides<br />

<strong>of</strong> a decision involving a possible bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder corporate conflict <strong>of</strong> interest.<br />

An otherwise essentially polycentric (nonjusticiable) management decision is transformed<br />

in<strong>to</strong> an essentially monocentric (justiciable) decision between conflicting fiduciary<br />

duties which conforms <strong>to</strong> the monocentric organization <strong>of</strong> our adjudica<strong>to</strong>ry<br />

system. In the Black-Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation, each class <strong>of</strong> securityholders<br />

has a call option on the equitable corporate ownership by the immediately<br />

senior (prior) class <strong>of</strong> securityholders. Thus, fiduciary conflicts regarding classes <strong>of</strong> the<br />

corporation's securityholders involve a nesting <strong>of</strong> monocentric conflicts and not a<br />

polycentric conflict.<br />

255. The existence <strong>of</strong> only one de fac<strong>to</strong> class <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders<br />

would occur, for example, when all inves<strong>to</strong>rs own either efficient market portfolios or<br />

equal proportions <strong>of</strong> the classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securities.


CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW<br />

[Vol. 20<br />

then the part (2) requirement <strong>of</strong> the new fiduciary articulation simplifies<br />

in<strong>to</strong> a requirement for unilateral side payments. A business<br />

judgment rule logically applies <strong>to</strong> judicial review <strong>of</strong> individual claims<br />

for unilateral side payments because there is no possible conflict <strong>of</strong><br />

fiduciary duties regarding such claims. 256<br />

In an individual claim for side payment, the securityholder<br />

would need <strong>to</strong> allege management's objective failure <strong>to</strong> meet the side<br />

payment requirement <strong>of</strong> the new fiduciary articulation. This would<br />

invoke entire-fairness careful-scrutiny <strong>with</strong> the burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> on<br />

management <strong>to</strong> show its compliance <strong>with</strong> the new fiduciary articulation.<br />

If management can show requisite "procedural fairness," then<br />

the burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> would shift <strong>to</strong> the securityholder <strong>to</strong> show management's<br />

noncompliance <strong>with</strong> the new fiduciary articulation: a reconstituted<br />

business judgment rule would apply.<br />

"Entire fairness" in this context logically means compliance <strong>with</strong><br />

the requirements <strong>of</strong> the new fiduciary articulation. "Procedural fairness"<br />

in this context might include a "fiduciary compliance group" in<br />

which: (1) an independent (e.g., tenured for a fixed term) pr<strong>of</strong>essional<br />

management committee makes the corporation's side-payment<br />

decisions - this might be "strong evidence" <strong>of</strong> fairness, 25 7 and<br />

(2) there is representation and ve<strong>to</strong> power (under the new fiduciary<br />

articulation) by each class <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders, <strong>with</strong><br />

complete disclosure by management <strong>of</strong> all material facts, regarding<br />

such side-payment decisions - this might shift the burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong><br />

back <strong>to</strong> the securityholder plaintiff challenging such decisions. 258<br />

In other words, some form <strong>of</strong> participation by the classes <strong>of</strong> the<br />

corporation's securityholders in the ongoing managerial decisionmaking<br />

process seems <strong>to</strong> be necessary in order <strong>to</strong> ensure protection<br />

<strong>of</strong> their economic interests. 25 9 In this context, a reconstituted<br />

256. See supra note 218 and accompanying text. An otherwise essentially<br />

monocentric (justiciable) management decision between conflicting fiduciary duties is<br />

transformed in<strong>to</strong> an essentially polycentric (nonjusticiable) decision which does not<br />

conform <strong>to</strong> the monocentric organization <strong>of</strong> our adjudica<strong>to</strong>ry system. Although the<br />

new fiduciary articulation's part (2) requirement for side payments might be considered<br />

as extinguished when there is only one de fac<strong>to</strong> class <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders,<br />

its function <strong>of</strong> compelling appropriate corporate class payments continues <strong>to</strong><br />

apply under such facts. For example, a claim for unilateral side payment seems <strong>to</strong> be<br />

appropriate when there is a wrongful denial <strong>of</strong> a dividend <strong>to</strong> the sole de fac<strong>to</strong> class <strong>of</strong><br />

the corporation's securityholders.<br />

257. Cf Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 709-10 n.7, 711.<br />

258. Cf id. at 703, 707.<br />

259. See Jensen & Meckling, supra note 20, at 338; Smith, Jr. & Warner, supra<br />

note 39, at 130. Whereas bondholder participation on the board <strong>of</strong> direc<strong>to</strong>rs might<br />

make such bondholders "control persons under the federal securities laws," McDaniel,<br />

supra note 71, at 441, and "'insiders' under the federal bankruptcy law," id., bondholder<br />

participation in the procedural-fairness structure would not do that because this<br />

structure is exclusively directed <strong>to</strong>ward the expropriation consequences <strong>of</strong> corporate


19861<br />

FIDUCIARY DUTY TO BONDHOLDERS<br />

business judgment rule prevents unjustified paralysis <strong>of</strong> the corporation.<br />

Thus, the objection that a "manager responsible <strong>to</strong> two conflicting<br />

interests is in fact answerable <strong>to</strong> neither" 260 is overcome by the<br />

new fiduciary articulation (securityholders' unanimity) <strong>with</strong> its procedural<br />

fairness structure.<br />

VI. CONCLUSION<br />

Our corporate fiduciary law is incongruous <strong>with</strong> the corporate-financial<br />

structure in which it is operationally embedded. Given the<br />

establishment <strong>of</strong> coherence between the theoretical structures <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

finance and corporate fiduciary law, adjustment <strong>of</strong> our corporate<br />

fiduciary law <strong>to</strong> the less-than-ideal conditions <strong>of</strong> particular cases<br />

follows as a matter <strong>of</strong> course.<br />

Economic conflicts among the classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders<br />

proceed from the generalized anomaly in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate<br />

current-market-value maximization, and such conflicts are<br />

intensified through the expropriation tendency by risk-averse s<strong>to</strong>ckholders.<br />

In particular, bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder unanticipated wealth<br />

expropriations are a consequence <strong>of</strong> the failure <strong>of</strong> contractual ordering<br />

<strong>to</strong> provide perfect protection for bondholders' and/or s<strong>to</strong>ckholders'<br />

wealth.<br />

An equal generic managerial fiduciary duty <strong>to</strong> all the corporation's<br />

securityholders arises out <strong>of</strong> the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value<br />

maximization, and managerial fiduciary duties <strong>to</strong> the<br />

classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's securityholders arise out <strong>of</strong> equitable<br />

ownerships <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets and cash flow by such classes<br />

under the Black-Scholes conception <strong>of</strong> the corporation. <strong>Fiduciary</strong><br />

law permits compensation and the imposition <strong>of</strong> a fiduciary obligation<br />

regarding bondholder-s<strong>to</strong>ckholder unanticipated wealth expropriations<br />

resulting from corporate decision-making. This fiduciary<br />

obligation is the neutralizing counterpart <strong>to</strong> the generalized anomaly<br />

in the rule <strong>of</strong> corporate current-market-value maximization. Formalized<br />

as "the new fiduciary articulation," it requires the corporation<br />

and its <strong>of</strong>ficers and direc<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong>: (1) maximize the present value <strong>of</strong><br />

the returns, evaluated <strong>with</strong> respect <strong>to</strong> all eventualities, on corporate<br />

assets, and (2) make corporate side payments so all classes <strong>of</strong> the corporation's<br />

securityholders receive more or less as much wealth as<br />

decisions which are made by others. (Although side payments through this structure<br />

would not be made while there is a significant chance <strong>of</strong> corporate bankruptcy, see<br />

supra note 192, this structure's moni<strong>to</strong>ring function continues <strong>to</strong> apply under such<br />

facts.)<br />

260. Easterbrook & Fischel, supra note 2, at 1192.


84 CREIGHTON LAW REVIEW [Vol. 20<br />

such classes would otherwise attain through alternative nonexpropriating<br />

corporate decisions.<br />

The new fiduciary articulation subsumes existing corporate fiduciary<br />

duties and overrides bond protective contractual provisions<br />

which violate its requirements. It implicitly forbids corporate decisions<br />

which increase the risk <strong>of</strong> corporate bankruptcy <strong>with</strong>out correspondingly<br />

maximizing the present value <strong>of</strong> the corporation's assets.<br />

Under it, in general, individual claims for side payments override derivative<br />

claims; and on entire-fairness careful-scrutiny rule overrides<br />

a business judgment rule and reconstitutes a business judgment rule<br />

through procedural-fairness standards.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!