02.12.2022 Views

Macroeconomics (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The presence of E t comes

from the fact that, in order

to buy the foreign bond, you

must first exchange domestic

currency for foreign currency.

The presence of Et e + 1

comes from the fact that, in

order to bring the funds back

next period, you will have to

exchange foreign currency for

domestic currency.

Domestic Bonds versus Foreign Bonds

As we look at the choice between domestic bonds and foreign bonds, we shall rely on

the assumption we introduced in Chapter 19: Financial investors, domestic or foreign,

go for the highest expected rate of return. This implies that, in equilibrium, both domestic

bonds and foreign bonds must have the same expected rate of return; otherwise,

investors would be willing to hold only one or the other, but not both, and this

could not be an equilibrium. (Like most economic relations, this relation is only an

approximation to reality and does not always hold. More on this in the Focus box “Sudden

Stops, Safe Havens, and the Limits of the Interest Parity Condition.”)

As we saw in Chapter 18 (equation (18.2)), this assumption implies that the following

arbitrage relation—the interest parity condition—must hold:

11 + i t 2 = 11 + i* t 2 a E t

Et e b

+ 1

where i t is the domestic interest rate, i* t is the foreign interest rate, E t is the current

exchange rate, and E e t +1 is the future expected exchange rate. The left side of the equation

gives the return, in terms of domestic currency, from holding domestic bonds. The

right side of the equation gives the expected return, also in terms of domestic currency,

from holding foreign bonds. In equilibrium, the two expected returns must be equal.

Multiply both sides by E e t +1 and reorganize to get

E t = 1 + i t

Et e + 1 (20.4)

1 + i* t

For now, we shall take the expected future exchange rate as given and denote it as

E e (we shall relax this assumption in Chapter 21). Under this assumption, and dropping

time indexes, the interest parity condition becomes

E = 1 + i

1 + i* E e (20.5)

This relation tells us that the current exchange rate depends on the domestic interest

rate, on the foreign interest rate, and on the expected future exchange rate:

An increase in the domestic interest rate leads to an increase in the exchange rate.

An increase in the foreign interest rate leads to a decrease in the exchange rate.

An increase in the expected future exchange rate leads to an increase in the current

exchange rate.

This relation plays a central role in the real world and will play a central role in this

chapter. To understand the relation further, consider the following example.

Consider financial investors—investors, for short—choosing between U.S.

bonds and Japanese bonds. Suppose that the one-year interest rate on U.S. bonds

is 2%, and the one-year interest rate on Japanese bonds is also 2%. Suppose that

the current exchange rate is 100 (one dollar is worth 100 yens), and the expected

exchange rate a year from now is also 100. Under these assumptions, both U.S. and

Japanese bonds have the same expected return in dollars, and the interest parity

condition holds.

Suppose now that investors now expect the exchange rate to be 10% higher a year

from now, so E e is now equal to 110. At an unchanged current exchange rate, U.S.

bonds are now much more attractive than Japanese bonds: U.S. bonds offer an interest

rate of 2% in dollars. Japanese bonds still offer an interest rate of 2% in yens, but the yen

a year from today are now expected to be worth 10% less in terms of dollars. In terms

426 The Open Economy Extensions

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!