04.01.2013 Views

PROCEEDINGS Volume 1 - ineag

PROCEEDINGS Volume 1 - ineag

PROCEEDINGS Volume 1 - ineag

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

subject to the static budget constraint<br />

and the non-negativity constraints in (11). In the static problem, optimization is carried out over the consumptionbequest<br />

policy. The portfolio choice is a residual decision. The choice is determined by the need to finance the<br />

optimal consumption-bequest policy.<br />

Theorem 3. (Ocone and Karatzas (1991), Detemple, Garcia and Rindisbacher (2003)). The optimal consumption<br />

and bequest policies are<br />

(20)<br />

where the state price density in (17) and is the unique solution of the equation<br />

The optimal portfolio is with<br />

where , and are the absolute risk tolerance measures<br />

and evaluated at optimal consumption and bequest. Moreover,<br />

where is the Malliavin derivative process that satisfies the linear stochastic differential equation<br />

and are the gradients of with respect<br />

to .<br />

The marginal cost of consumption is the state price density adjusted by a Lagrange multiplier so as to account for<br />

the need to satisfy the static budget constraint. Thus, and the optimal consumption-bequest<br />

policies (20) follow. The equation for is then dictated by the need to saturate the budget constraint. Optimal wealth<br />

is the present value of future consumption and bequest<br />

The optimal portfolio determines the volatility of wealth. To identify it, it suffices to calculate the volatility<br />

coefficients on the left and right hand sides of (26). This can be done by applying the Clark-Ocone formula (see<br />

Ocone and Karatzas (1991) and Detemple, Garcia and Rindisbacher (2003)) and the rules of Malliavin calculus (see<br />

Nualart (1995) for a comprehensive treatment). The leads to (22)-(23).<br />

The portfolio component (22) corresponds to the mean-variance term (13). The new element is that the leading term,<br />

which was written as a ratio of derivatives of the value function in the previous formula, is now seen to represent the<br />

cost of optimal risk tolerance. The portfolio component (23) is the dynamic hedge due to fluctuations in the state<br />

variables. This dynamic hedge has two fundamental parts. The first is motivated by fluctuations in the interest rate.<br />

This is the term depending on in (24). It represents an interest rate hedge. The second is due to fluctuations<br />

in the market prices of risk. It comprises the terms in in (24) and represents a market price of risk hedge.<br />

The two hedges can be written as<br />

20<br />

(19)<br />

(21)<br />

(22)<br />

(23)<br />

(24)<br />

(25)<br />

(26)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!