17.03.2013 Views

Rentierism, Dependency and Sovereignty in Central Asia

Rentierism, Dependency and Sovereignty in Central Asia

Rentierism, Dependency and Sovereignty in Central Asia

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

61 st Political Studies Association Annual Conference<br />

Transform<strong>in</strong>g Politics: New Synergies<br />

19 - 21 April 2011<br />

Novotel London West<br />

Panel: ‘Embedd<strong>in</strong>g Democracy’<br />

<strong>Rentierism</strong>, <strong>Dependency</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Sovereignty</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong><br />

Dr Wojciech Ostrowski<br />

University of Dundee<br />

Centre for Energy, Petroleum <strong>and</strong> M<strong>in</strong>eral Law <strong>and</strong> Policy<br />

Carnegie Build<strong>in</strong>g<br />

University of Dundee<br />

Dundee<br />

DD1 4HN<br />

Scotl<strong>and</strong><br />

w.ostrowski@dundee.ac.uk<br />

Do not cite or circulate without author’s permission<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

1


Twenty years after becom<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dependent states, all five <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics can be broadly<br />

characterised as rentier <strong>and</strong> semi/quasi-rentier states. The ‘classic’ rentier states Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong><br />

Turkmenistan rely on rent (wealth) that derives directly from the sale of oil <strong>and</strong> gas while semirentiers<br />

Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan rely on rent that comes from a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of <strong>in</strong>direct taxation<br />

of labour remittances obta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong> Russia, <strong>in</strong>ternational aid, leas<strong>in</strong>g access to<br />

territory <strong>and</strong> drug trade. Uzbekistan, which is heavily dependent on the sale of cotton, gold, gas on<br />

the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets as well as labour remittances, <strong>and</strong>, to a lesser degree leas<strong>in</strong>g access to<br />

territory falls somewhere between Kazakhstan, Turkmenistan on the one h<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Kyrgyzstan,<br />

Tajikistan on the other. The economic composition of the <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n region, which began<br />

tak<strong>in</strong>g its current shape with the unprecedented <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> oil prices <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of 2000s,<br />

starts mirror<strong>in</strong>g the Middle Eastern style “division of labour” that developed between oil-rich Gulf<br />

<strong>and</strong> oil-poor Arab countries, as well as Pakistan <strong>and</strong> other states which have been greatly<br />

dependent on labour remittances that their citizens earn <strong>in</strong> the oil-rich states (Chaudhry 1989;<br />

Addleton 1992; H<strong>in</strong>nebusch 2003)<br />

The dependency of the <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics on rent has a far reach<strong>in</strong>g impact on these<br />

countries’ foreign policy, their relationship with Russia <strong>and</strong> state sovereignty. In the case of<br />

Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong> Turkmenistan, lack of viable alternatives to oil <strong>and</strong> gas exports <strong>and</strong> full<br />

dependency – until very recently - on the Russian controlled pipel<strong>in</strong>e system has substantially<br />

narrowed their room for manoeuvre <strong>and</strong> allowed Russia to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> the upper h<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> its<br />

relationship with <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n oil <strong>and</strong> gas exporters. In sharp dist<strong>in</strong>ction to Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong><br />

Turkmenistan, Uzbek overreliance on cotton allowed the rul<strong>in</strong>g regime to pursue the most<br />

<strong>in</strong>dependent foreign policy <strong>in</strong> the region the durability of which is, however, highly questionable<br />

due to unstable cotton prices on the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets. Kyrgyz <strong>and</strong> Tajik dependency on<br />

foreign aid, labour remittances <strong>and</strong> leas<strong>in</strong>g access to territory forced rul<strong>in</strong>g regimes to largely<br />

subord<strong>in</strong>ate their foreign policies to the politics of the regional or <strong>in</strong>ternational powers on which its<br />

economic survival currently depends on. The dependency on outside ‘patrons’ expla<strong>in</strong>s both the<br />

presence of the US <strong>and</strong> Russian military basis on Kyrgyz territory <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan’s strong ties to<br />

Russia. In short, the key role that rent plays <strong>in</strong> the survival of the <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n states has either<br />

hampered these countries’ sovereignty, or made its ma<strong>in</strong>tenance very difficult.<br />

<strong>Rentierism</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Sovereignty</strong><br />

The rentier state concept attempts to elucidate the impact that rent derived especially from the sale<br />

of oil <strong>and</strong> gas on the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets has on the nature of the states as well as the political<br />

systems of the resources <strong>and</strong> energy-rich counties. Thus, those work<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> the rentier state<br />

tradition focus on those states <strong>in</strong> which the economy is dom<strong>in</strong>ated by rents rather than by<br />

productive enterprises like agriculture <strong>and</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> where the orig<strong>in</strong> of the <strong>in</strong>come is<br />

external. In addition, the rent is generated by small elite, the majority be<strong>in</strong>g only <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the<br />

distribution or utilization of it, <strong>and</strong> the state be<strong>in</strong>g the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal recipient of these rents. A rentier<br />

state accord<strong>in</strong>gly plays a central role <strong>in</strong> distribut<strong>in</strong>g this wealth to the population (Beblawi 1987:<br />

51–53).<br />

The rentier state concept was <strong>in</strong>itially crafted by the North African <strong>and</strong> Middle Eastern<br />

scholars (Mahdavy 1970; Beblawi <strong>and</strong> Luciani 1987; Skocpol 1982; Chaudhry 1989; Crystal<br />

1991; Brynen 1992; Shambayati 1994; Okruhlik 1999) <strong>and</strong> over time has been applied to other<br />

areas of the world, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g sub-Saharan Africa (Yates 1996; Clark 1997; Frynas 2004; Soares de<br />

Oliveira 2007) <strong>and</strong> South America (Karl 1997). In recent years, with various degrees of success,<br />

the rentier state concept was also applied to post-Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> <strong>and</strong> Caucasus (Kuru 2002;<br />

Ishiyama 2002; Franke et al. 2009) <strong>and</strong> even to Russia (Luong 2000; Kim 2003; Wood 2007). The<br />

fact that the rentier state concept travelled across space <strong>and</strong> time <strong>and</strong> endured as a valid notion is a<br />

testimony to the <strong>in</strong>itial analysis by the Middle Eastern scholars who correctly decoded <strong>and</strong><br />

described the dynamics of the rentier state <strong>and</strong> its impact on the political systems of the non-<br />

Western, post-colonial (rentier) states (Ross 2001). Terry Karl, <strong>in</strong> her study of Venezuela written<br />

almost thirty years after the rentier state concept was first applied, argued that <strong>in</strong> essence all rentier<br />

2<br />

Copyright PSA 2011


states can be characterized by the same fundamental economic policy pattern: ‘maximiz<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

external extraction of rents for subsequent distribution through public spend<strong>in</strong>g accord<strong>in</strong>g to a<br />

political logic’ (Karl 1997: 197).<br />

At the same time, the success that the rentier state concept enjoyed has lead a situation <strong>in</strong><br />

which the notion has been overstretched. The critiques po<strong>in</strong>ted out that the concept was applied to<br />

various cases that did not necessarily meet Hazem Beblawi’s criteria, hence, faced the danger of<br />

los<strong>in</strong>g its <strong>in</strong>tellectual appeal (Okruhlik 1999; Smith 2004). One of the key problems have been<br />

these states whose economies over-rely on remittances, outside aid (rent) <strong>and</strong> for these reasons<br />

have been quickly grouped together with the oil-gas-rich countries. Giacomo Luciani correctly<br />

noted that while remittances are an important flow of <strong>in</strong>come - which conta<strong>in</strong>s a rent component -<br />

it does not accrue directly to the state, therefore the term rentier state is not fitt<strong>in</strong>g here. He went<br />

on to argue that the state may attempt to tax the <strong>in</strong>come of economic migrants, but is <strong>in</strong> no position<br />

to do so before it is repatriated. Thus, economies which rely on remittances accord<strong>in</strong>g to Luciani<br />

do not constitute a full blown rentier state but rather a rentier economy (1987: 68-70). Beblawi<br />

called these sorts of states ‘semi-rentiers without oil’ (1987: 59)<br />

The dist<strong>in</strong>ction between oil-gas-rich rentier states <strong>and</strong> semi-rentier states that rely on<br />

remittances, <strong>in</strong>ternational aid has important implications for the state-society relationships <strong>and</strong><br />

arguably also an impact on a country’s foreign relationships. In the traditionally understood rentier<br />

state, rent provided the state with an extremely large <strong>and</strong> powerful economic <strong>and</strong> social role that<br />

has fostered the long term stability of the rul<strong>in</strong>g regimes <strong>and</strong> has allowed it to survive <strong>in</strong>ternal as<br />

well as external crises (Anderson 1987; Ayubi 2001; Karl 2007; Omgba 2009). The rul<strong>in</strong>g elites of<br />

the semi-rentier state which do not have access to abundant <strong>in</strong>come, are expected to be affected by<br />

changes <strong>in</strong> the regional as well as the global economy <strong>and</strong> are <strong>in</strong>evitably less stable, <strong>and</strong> thus,<br />

likely to adapt to the chang<strong>in</strong>g environment (Brynen 1992). For <strong>in</strong>stance, they are likely to<br />

liberalize some aspects of their economies <strong>and</strong> at times political life but do not go so far as to fully<br />

democratize (H<strong>in</strong>nebusch 2000). By the same token, the foreign policy of the semi-rentier state is<br />

more prone to change <strong>and</strong> also much more dynamic. This is due to the simple fact that the labour<br />

remittances or <strong>in</strong>ternational aid constitute the basis for a much weaker <strong>and</strong> less stable alliance<br />

between rul<strong>in</strong>g regimes <strong>and</strong> regional, <strong>in</strong>ternational powers than oil <strong>and</strong> gas. Hence, semi-rentier<br />

states can attempt to switch alliances from one patron to another (Clapham 1996). The oil-gas-rich<br />

rentier states are different <strong>in</strong> this respect s<strong>in</strong>ce they are often <strong>in</strong>terlocked <strong>in</strong> long term economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> military relationships with outside powers. These relationships tend to endure – ma<strong>in</strong>ly due to<br />

the physical nature of oil <strong>and</strong> gas - regardless of major political shifts at the regional or global<br />

level (Noreng 2002; Shaxson 2007). At the same time, the exist<strong>in</strong>g difference between rentier<br />

states <strong>and</strong> semi-rentier states should not obscure the fact that – at its most fundamental level - both<br />

foreign policies are entangled <strong>and</strong> shaped by various types of dependencies; dependencies which<br />

<strong>in</strong>evitably pose vital questions concern<strong>in</strong>g state survival, state security <strong>and</strong> ultimately the<br />

sovereignty of rentier <strong>and</strong> semi-rentier states as the example of <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> confirms.<br />

<strong>Rentierism</strong>, <strong>Dependency</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong><br />

The rentierism <strong>and</strong> economic dependency <strong>in</strong> post-Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> is a direct result of two<br />

legacies a) the Soviet Union <strong>and</strong> b) the neo-liberal project which reached its high po<strong>in</strong>t with the<br />

collapse of the communist regimes <strong>in</strong> Europe <strong>and</strong>, all but name, <strong>in</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. The Soviet Union, due to<br />

its long term dom<strong>in</strong>ation of <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> shaped it economically <strong>and</strong> politically while neo-liberal<br />

enterprise allowed the post-Soviets elites to consolidate key structural elements of the Soviet<br />

system that proved vital to their rule which has been traditionally based on patronage <strong>and</strong> favour.<br />

Consequently the collapse of the Soviet Union <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>, at the time a much hailed ‘rupture’,<br />

overtime came to signify merely a launch of a post-Soviet narrative - where stress from the outset<br />

was firmly put on the Soviet element – rather than a creation of someth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>tr<strong>in</strong>sically new <strong>and</strong><br />

unique.<br />

Today’s dependency of the key post-Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n economies on rent <strong>in</strong>come, the<br />

orig<strong>in</strong>s of which are external, rather than by productive enterprises is largely a legacy of the role<br />

3<br />

Copyright PSA 2011


that <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics had <strong>in</strong> the Soviet economy as suppliers of cotton, oil, gas <strong>and</strong> m<strong>in</strong>erals<br />

to exist<strong>in</strong>g manufactur<strong>in</strong>g centres, located primarily <strong>in</strong> the Russian areas of the USSR. The role of<br />

<strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> <strong>in</strong> the Soviet Union economy was further entrenched by a net of transport networks<br />

which were built to serve the larger Soviet project (Odum <strong>and</strong> Johnson 2004). The resource<br />

dependent nature of the <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n economy on the eve of <strong>in</strong>dependence was actively<br />

re<strong>in</strong>forced by post-Soviet rul<strong>in</strong>g elites. Their actions were motivated by two factors a) lack of any<br />

apparent alternatives to commodity based economies <strong>and</strong> b) their unbridled lust for power <strong>and</strong><br />

wealth.<br />

From the late Khrushchev era until early <strong>in</strong>to Gorbachev’s rule, regional <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n<br />

cadres were groomed <strong>and</strong> controlled by Moscow through an elaborate system of patron-client<br />

relationships (Roy 2000; Dave 2007; Khalid 2007). The prime function of the Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n<br />

elites, who firmly sat on the top of their own patron-client pyramid, was to assure that the<br />

republics met their quotas (someth<strong>in</strong>g that they often failed to do) <strong>and</strong> to keep the population <strong>in</strong><br />

check <strong>and</strong> under control (someth<strong>in</strong>g that they almost never failed to do successfully). The <strong>Central</strong><br />

<strong>Asia</strong>n Soviet elites, who much to their own surprise overnight (Olcott 2002), became rulers of the<br />

newly <strong>in</strong>dependent states choose to rely on the exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries <strong>and</strong> patron-client based political<br />

structures as long as these allowed them to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> relative social peace <strong>and</strong> successfully keep<br />

them <strong>in</strong> power (Luong <strong>and</strong> We<strong>in</strong>thal 2001).<br />

Whereas the Soviet Union set the material <strong>and</strong> political stage on which <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n<br />

elites had been operat<strong>in</strong>g it is important to recognise that the post-Soviet economic structure was<br />

also significantly shaped by the nature of the economic order that developed outside the Soviet<br />

Union <strong>and</strong> the larger socialist world <strong>in</strong> the late 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s. It should be remembered that<br />

1991, a year <strong>in</strong> which the <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> republics ga<strong>in</strong>ed their <strong>in</strong>dependence, was also one of the<br />

high po<strong>in</strong>ts of the neo-liberal project, a project which significantly aided the transformations of the<br />

Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics <strong>in</strong>to rentier <strong>and</strong> semi-rentier economies <strong>and</strong> re<strong>in</strong>forced <strong>and</strong><br />

deepened separations <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n economy which is today reflected <strong>in</strong> the regional<br />

“division of labour”.<br />

In reference to the first po<strong>in</strong>t, the price liberalisation that followed the dis<strong>in</strong>tegration of the<br />

USSR, <strong>and</strong> which was actively encouraged by the advocates of the neo-liberal enterprise, <strong>in</strong>stantly<br />

rewarded countries rich <strong>in</strong> natural resources <strong>and</strong> their rulers. The amounts of money to which<br />

yesterday’s apparatchiks ga<strong>in</strong>ed access was unimag<strong>in</strong>able to them only few years earlier, the<br />

‘success’ was dazzl<strong>in</strong>g. Thus, the benefits that the liberalisation brought <strong>and</strong> the prospects of<br />

open<strong>in</strong>g global markets ensured that the foundations of a rentier post-Soviet economy <strong>and</strong> its<br />

specific mentality were firmly put <strong>in</strong> place.<br />

In reference to the second po<strong>in</strong>t, the key <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong><br />

Uzbekistan, which dur<strong>in</strong>g the Soviet Union were vital to the regional economy <strong>and</strong> its economic<br />

future, managed to largely ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> consolidate their dom<strong>in</strong>ant positions <strong>in</strong> the 1990s, whereas<br />

Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan resource-poor <strong>and</strong> heavily subsidized by Moscow were <strong>in</strong> steady<br />

decl<strong>in</strong>e. The ‘w<strong>in</strong>ners’ <strong>in</strong> the global neo-liberal ‘cas<strong>in</strong>o’ were those <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics that<br />

could offer commodities (ma<strong>in</strong>ly oil <strong>and</strong> gas) which Russia <strong>and</strong> the external world still wanted. As<br />

a result of this two decades after the collapse of the Soviet Union Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan were<br />

widely grouped together with the ‘excluded’ – from the neo-liberal project - regions of the global<br />

South (Rotberg 2004), which often through a shadow crim<strong>in</strong>al economy tried to re-<strong>in</strong>tegrate<br />

themselves <strong>in</strong>to the global economy. Philip Le Billion argued that the activities of those excluded<br />

from the neo-liberal enterprise revolve around tax evasion, tax paradises <strong>and</strong> smuggl<strong>in</strong>g schemes,<br />

some <strong>in</strong>volve drug traffick<strong>in</strong>g, money launder<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> illegal migration (2001: 576). All of the<br />

above are a firm feature of today’s Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan <strong>and</strong> are largely responsible for their<br />

political <strong>and</strong> economical decl<strong>in</strong>e as well as systemic political violence.<br />

Uzbekistan <strong>and</strong> Turkmenistan<br />

The legacy of Soviet patterns of development have been most visible <strong>in</strong> Uzbekistan, where cotton<br />

constituted a vital part of the economy from the Second World War onwards, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> Turkmenistan<br />

4<br />

Copyright PSA 2011


which besides be<strong>in</strong>g a cotton producer also became an important exporter of natural gas s<strong>in</strong>ce the<br />

1970s. In the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s both countries substantially benefited from buoyant cotton<br />

prices which allowed rul<strong>in</strong>g regimes to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> the status quo without any major economical <strong>and</strong><br />

political reforms. In the 2000s, both regimes tried to preserve the situation from the 1990s. Hence,<br />

Uzbekistan deepened its dependency on cotton <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> later years gold, gas <strong>and</strong> on labour<br />

remittances <strong>and</strong> Turkmenistan turned almost fully to gas exports. The Turkmen’s regime<br />

concentration on gas exports accelerated after the rise <strong>in</strong> gas prices <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 2000s,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the failure of the ISI program <strong>in</strong>troduced by the government <strong>in</strong> the late 1990s.<br />

In Uzbekistan the cotton production can be traced back to the n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century when it<br />

was one of the key suppliers of cotton to Tsarist Russia. Cotton production rapidly exp<strong>and</strong>ed <strong>in</strong><br />

the Soviet Uzbekistan <strong>in</strong> 1950s <strong>and</strong> 1960s <strong>and</strong> by the 1980s the republic was qualified as a<br />

‘monocultural economy’ with some 65 per cent of cultivated l<strong>and</strong> be<strong>in</strong>g devoted to cotton<br />

production. The so-called ‘white gold’ accounted for about two-thirds of the Republic’s<br />

agricultural output <strong>and</strong> the Uzbek SSR produced 62 per cent of all cotton grown <strong>in</strong> the Soviet<br />

Union <strong>in</strong> late Soviet times. On the eve of <strong>in</strong>dependence, Uzbekistan was the fourth biggest cotton<br />

producer <strong>in</strong> the world <strong>and</strong> the second lead<strong>in</strong>g exporter (Spechler 2008: 19-20).<br />

The much talked about mechanization of the countryside – part of the so-called<br />

equalization policy (Rodgers 1974; Liebowitz 1987; Ozornoy 1991), which aimed at equaliz<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the levels of economic development <strong>and</strong> liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards of the country’s diverse nationalities <strong>and</strong><br />

regions - did not take place. In the late 1980s more manual workers – largely woman, children <strong>and</strong><br />

students – were pick<strong>in</strong>g cotton by h<strong>and</strong> than 20 years before. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to one author, <strong>in</strong> 1981<br />

about 35 per cent of the overall harvest was h<strong>and</strong> picked (Gleason 1991: 348). In the mid-1980s <strong>in</strong><br />

Uzbekistan more than half (around 58 percent) of the population worked <strong>in</strong> agriculture. The<br />

overwhelm<strong>in</strong>g majority of those liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the country-side were ethnic Uzbeks whereas <strong>in</strong>dustrial<br />

management <strong>and</strong> skilled labour was primarily comprised of Russians <strong>and</strong> other Slavs who<br />

populated two urban centres (Luong 2002: 68; Lub<strong>in</strong> 1984). F<strong>in</strong>ally, most of the cotton output<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g the Soviet times went to cotton mills <strong>in</strong> the Russian republic. It was then sold on the<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternational markets through centralized foreign trade agencies, ‘with little benefit to the growers’<br />

(Pomfret 2006: 143-144).<br />

On face value, the relationship between the imperial core <strong>and</strong> the colonized periphery<br />

closely mirrors the type of dependency relationship that could be found <strong>in</strong> the Middle East<br />

(H<strong>in</strong>nebusch 2003: 35). However, <strong>in</strong> the Soviet Union the actual situation on the ground was much<br />

more complicated <strong>and</strong> not as clear-cut as <strong>in</strong> other parts of the world (i.e. post-colonial sub-Saharan<br />

Africa <strong>and</strong> South America). It should be kept <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d that at the time of <strong>in</strong>dependence, the Uzbek<br />

economy was more diversified than the economies of other <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics. It <strong>in</strong>cluded<br />

agriculture, light <strong>and</strong> heavy <strong>in</strong>dustry, <strong>and</strong> branches of primary products (Gleason 2003: 117).<br />

Furthermore, <strong>in</strong> Uzbekistan the level of literacy, public health, <strong>and</strong> education for women exceeded<br />

regional levels (Spechler 2008: 26). Yet, the preservation of those Soviet ‘achievements’ proved to<br />

be highly problematic to the Uzbek post-Soviet regime which <strong>in</strong> the face of the post-Soviet chaos<br />

largely ab<strong>and</strong>oned other sectors of the <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> favour of cotton <strong>and</strong> thus began a process of<br />

steady retreat of the state with far reach<strong>in</strong>g consequences for education, public health <strong>and</strong> the role<br />

of women <strong>in</strong> society (Kamp 2004; Spechler 2008).<br />

The turn towards the cotton <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> the post-Soviet period was significantly<br />

accelerated due to the favourable cotton prices on the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets <strong>in</strong> 1992-96, a move<br />

which left a last<strong>in</strong>g legacy on today’s Uzbekistan (Luong <strong>and</strong> We<strong>in</strong>thal 2001). Deniz K<strong>and</strong>iyoti<br />

argued that <strong>in</strong> order to fully underst<strong>and</strong> post-Soviet trajectories of the <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics,<br />

students of the region should not only take <strong>in</strong>to account ‘the historical specificities of their colonial<br />

encounters but also very different modalities <strong>and</strong> temporalities of their <strong>in</strong>sertion <strong>in</strong>to world<br />

capitalist markets’ (2002: 282). It is argued here that the <strong>in</strong>itial policies <strong>and</strong> choices of the post-<br />

Soviet regime firmly l<strong>in</strong>ked the future of the country to the volatile commodity prices on the<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternational markets. This argument is supported by the fact that despite the collapse of cotton<br />

prices towards the end of the 1990s, <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 2000s the primary commodities,<br />

together with cotton fibre, still accounted for 75 percent of merch<strong>and</strong>ise exports, with cotton alone<br />

5<br />

Copyright PSA 2011


account<strong>in</strong>g for about 40 percent (Gleason 2003: 119). In the second decade of <strong>in</strong>dependence the<br />

Uzbek government attempted at cushion<strong>in</strong>g the fall <strong>in</strong> cotton prices with a partial liberalization of<br />

its economy. Yet, the cotton <strong>in</strong>dustry rema<strong>in</strong>ed subject to state orders <strong>and</strong> state control.<br />

The w<strong>in</strong>ners <strong>in</strong> the new Uzbekistan have been those at the apex of power <strong>and</strong> their clients<br />

(Coll<strong>in</strong>s 2009: 270; Ilkhamov 2007). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to a report by the International Crisis Group,<br />

money obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the sale of cotton circulates with<strong>in</strong> a small elite, <strong>and</strong> rarely if ever enters the<br />

agricultural f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g system: ‘[o]ne estimate is that as little as 10 to 15 per cent of the <strong>in</strong>come<br />

generated by the sale of cotton goes back <strong>in</strong>to agriculture thus to the farmers (2005: 4-5). The<br />

development of the oligarchy that governs today’s Uzbek cotton <strong>in</strong>dustry goes back to the 1970s<br />

when a ‘clear-cut cotton nomenklatura had developed, with ‘cotton-barons’ dom<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

[cotton] complex, mak<strong>in</strong>g use of falsified output <strong>and</strong> yield data, illicit trade practices <strong>and</strong> forced<br />

labour’ (Spoor 1993: 11; see also: Rumer 1989; Vaksberg 1991; Khalid 2007). The effects of the<br />

so-called ‘cotton curse’ are best visible <strong>in</strong> the large numbers of labour migrants to Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong><br />

Russian. In 2004-2008 as many as 2.5 millions Uzbeks left the country - a fact that the Uzbek<br />

government has officially denied – <strong>and</strong> by 2008 remittances consisted 13 per cent of the Uzbek<br />

economy (ICG 2010a: 3). The workers who until the recent <strong>in</strong>troduction of Western Union carried<br />

their earn<strong>in</strong>gs back home <strong>in</strong> cash were subject to <strong>in</strong>direct taxation by the state agencies at various<br />

steps of their journey (Coll<strong>in</strong>s 2009: 268).<br />

Other important sectors of the post-Soviet Uzbek rentier economy have been gold <strong>and</strong><br />

energy sales – ma<strong>in</strong>ly gas – which account for 14% of export value. Gas is transported through the<br />

Russian-owned Gazprom pipel<strong>in</strong>e network via Kazakhstan (Spechler <strong>and</strong> Spechler 2009: 358-<br />

359). F<strong>in</strong>ally, towards the end of the 1990s <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the first half of 2000s, the Uzbek government<br />

established strategic alliances with the US which further deep the rentier character of the Uzbek<br />

state <strong>and</strong> economy (Hiro 2009: 173-176). In 2000 Uzbekistan received considerable amounts of<br />

equipment under the Foreign Military F<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g programme. Military alliances deepened on the<br />

eve of the ‘war on terror’ which led to the establishment of a small military base <strong>in</strong> Uzbekistan <strong>in</strong><br />

which around one thous<strong>and</strong> personnel were stationed. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the first year the base earned the<br />

Uzbek government around $450 millions <strong>in</strong> grants <strong>and</strong> credits (Spechler <strong>and</strong> Spechler 2009: 366).<br />

However, the military alliance was abruptly term<strong>in</strong>ated by the Uzbek regime <strong>in</strong> 2005 (Rumer<br />

2006), prompt<strong>in</strong>g a turn towards Russia <strong>and</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a <strong>and</strong> search for new grants, credits <strong>and</strong> deals<br />

(Hiro 2009: 190).<br />

Today’s Uzbekistan is a well diversified rentier state whose roots can be directly traced<br />

back to the Tsarist <strong>and</strong> Soviet period. The regime survives primarily due to rent obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the<br />

sale of cotton, gold <strong>and</strong> gas which allowed it to fuel patrimonial networks <strong>and</strong> to pay for fairly<br />

large military <strong>and</strong> security apparatus. In this respect the Uzbek regime is very similar to neopatrimonial<br />

regimes which have ruled various parts of the Middle East (H<strong>in</strong>nebusch 2006) as well<br />

as sub-Saharan Africa (Le V<strong>in</strong>e 1980; Bratton <strong>and</strong> van de Walle 1994; Bratton <strong>and</strong> van de Walle<br />

1997). The remittances <strong>in</strong>directly allow the government to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> social peace <strong>and</strong> subsidise<br />

wages of the local bureaucracies even though the regime does not want to acknowledge this.<br />

Turkmenistan is another <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n state with a rentier character, which even more than<br />

Uzbekistan, took its shape dur<strong>in</strong>g the Soviet period <strong>and</strong> blossomed <strong>in</strong> the post-<strong>in</strong>dependent period.<br />

The critical juncture <strong>in</strong> the development of the Turkmen rentier state was the period<br />

towards the end of the 1970s <strong>and</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1980s when natural gas came to dom<strong>in</strong>ate<br />

the republic’s economy. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to one author as early as 1970 the SSR Turkmenistan supplied<br />

24 percent of natural gas <strong>in</strong> the Soviet Union whose share rapidly rose to just under 33 percent by<br />

1975 (Ebel 2000: 4). Today Turkmenistan ranks as the word’s fourth largest potential gas<br />

producer, after Russia, the United States, <strong>and</strong> Iran. Outside the natural gas sector, the <strong>in</strong>dustrial<br />

base of the Soviet Turkmenistan was grossly underdeveloped <strong>and</strong> traces of the modern <strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

(particularly textile enterprises) that existed survived solely thanks to the Soviet central subsidies.<br />

The Soviet planners left the republic underdeveloped largely due to its remote geographical<br />

position.<br />

Another important element of the Turkmen economy – similarly to Uzbekistan – was<br />

cotton production. In the 1980s, more than 50 percent of the republics population was employed<br />

6<br />

Copyright PSA 2011


on the cotton fields (Gleason 1991: 342), its sole major agriculture product. A major boost to<br />

cotton production was provided by the completion of the Karakum Canal (over more than 1,200<br />

kilometers) which diverts water from the Amu Darya <strong>in</strong>to the southern desert regions of<br />

Uzbekistan <strong>and</strong> Turkmenistan. On the eve of <strong>in</strong>dependence cotton, oil <strong>and</strong> gas made up 80 per cent<br />

of Turkmenistan’s <strong>in</strong>dustrial economy (Gleason 2003: 107). Furthermore, the cotton <strong>in</strong>dustry was<br />

still the largest employer <strong>in</strong> the country whereas gas guaranteed the most significant revenues to<br />

the national government (Anceschi 2009: 66).<br />

Lead<strong>in</strong>g on, similarly to Uzbekistan the bulk of the cotton produced <strong>in</strong> Turkmenistan<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g the Soviet times was preceded <strong>and</strong> manufactured outside the republic <strong>in</strong> the northern<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustrial centers <strong>in</strong> Russia <strong>and</strong> Ukra<strong>in</strong>e. Similarly gas was sent through an <strong>in</strong>ter-Union pipel<strong>in</strong>e<br />

system, ‘to the European zone of the Soviet Union, whose high dem<strong>and</strong> for fuel could only be<br />

satisfied by massive imports of oil <strong>and</strong> gas from other regions of the USSR’ (Anceschi 2009: 66).<br />

The collapse of the Soviet Union strengthened the regime’s dependency on gas <strong>and</strong> cotton as well<br />

as on the pre-exist<strong>in</strong>g relationships with its economic partners. As <strong>in</strong> the case of Uzbekistan the<br />

key <strong>in</strong> Turkmenistan’s quick transition towards a rentier economy was price liberalization which<br />

followed the dis<strong>in</strong>tegration of the Soviet Union ‘[t]his enabled Turkmenistan to charge world<br />

market prices for the gas it supplied to its former Soviet era customers <strong>in</strong> Ukra<strong>in</strong>e, Georgia,<br />

Russia, <strong>and</strong> other countries’ (Gleason 2003: 109). In the first two years of the post-Soviet Union<br />

period, Turkmenistan was second only to Russia <strong>in</strong> benefit<strong>in</strong>g for adjust<strong>in</strong>g prices to world levels<br />

(Ancseschi 2009: 72). On the negative side Turkmenistan like Uzbekistan very quickly became<br />

over-exposed to volatile – or cyclical - energy prices on the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets (Stevens 2008)<br />

<strong>and</strong> firmly l<strong>in</strong>ked their post-Soviet fate with the Russian controlled pipel<strong>in</strong>e system, a dependency<br />

which was only recently broken.<br />

It appears that the new Turkmen regime was acutely aware of the situation <strong>in</strong> which it<br />

found itself. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s the Turkmen government actively<br />

participated <strong>in</strong> efforts to build a pipel<strong>in</strong>e which would run under the Caspian Sea <strong>and</strong> connect<br />

Turkmenistan to non-Russian markets. Those efforts largely failed by 2000. In the next phase,<br />

Turkmenistan <strong>in</strong> classic rentier-state-style, embarked on an economic program of ISI. S<strong>in</strong>ce the<br />

mid-1990s the government f<strong>in</strong>anced the development of a modern textile <strong>in</strong>dustry process<strong>in</strong>g<br />

domestic cotton <strong>and</strong> silk, which became the centrepiece of ISI (Pomfret 2006: 93). However, the<br />

much hyped modernization resulted <strong>in</strong> the production of low-quality manufactured goods that<br />

could not compete on the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets (Ancseschi 2009: 75). The ma<strong>in</strong> reason for this<br />

failure was a lack of technical capacity.<br />

At the same time, the Turkmen regime did not attempt at far reach<strong>in</strong>g economic<br />

liberalization. Rather two key sectors of gas <strong>and</strong> cotton stayed <strong>in</strong> government h<strong>and</strong>s, which acted<br />

to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> strict adm<strong>in</strong>istration <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial control over them. State controls over the economy<br />

allowed the rul<strong>in</strong>g regime to fuel <strong>and</strong> uphold a vast patronage system (Coll<strong>in</strong>s 2006: 303). Kiren<br />

Chaudhry has argued that historically rulers of the rentier states <strong>in</strong> the Middle East were also<br />

extremely hostile to the free market which they viewed as be<strong>in</strong>g politically dangerous because ‘a<br />

function<strong>in</strong>g market provides opportunities for mobility that undercut l<strong>in</strong>eages <strong>and</strong> traditional rights<br />

of privileges, thus threaten<strong>in</strong>g the status quo. Market creates <strong>in</strong>equalities <strong>in</strong> wealth that may not<br />

match exist<strong>in</strong>g patterns of <strong>in</strong>come distribution, status, power, <strong>and</strong> entitlements; they dislocate<br />

groups <strong>in</strong> both the political <strong>and</strong> economic realms’ (1994: 4).<br />

Follow<strong>in</strong>g the same logic of non liberalisation <strong>and</strong> uphold<strong>in</strong>g exist<strong>in</strong>g structures strategy<br />

the Turkmen regime also successfully attempted at susta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g parts of the Soviet welfare system<br />

throughout the 1990s, as argued by Richard Pomfret: ‘[t]he universal benefits from the Soviet era,<br />

such as pensions at 57 for woman <strong>and</strong> 62 for men, were supplemented by free provision of gas,<br />

electricity, water, <strong>and</strong> slat for residential use’ (2006: 90). Aga<strong>in</strong> the behaviour of the Turkmen<br />

regime mirrors that of the Middle Eastern <strong>and</strong> North African regimes. John Entelis argued that <strong>in</strong><br />

the Middle Eastern <strong>and</strong> North African states ‘a sort of “rul<strong>in</strong>g barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g” was struck by the<br />

leadership with its people at <strong>in</strong>dependence under which the populace gave up its rights to<br />

<strong>in</strong>dependent political activity <strong>in</strong> return for the state’s provision of social welfare’ (1996: 45). This<br />

does not mean, however, that an ord<strong>in</strong>ary person or every region <strong>in</strong> the country is a w<strong>in</strong>ner.<br />

7<br />

Copyright PSA 2011


In rentier states, state <strong>in</strong>vestment funds often are disproportionately directed towards the<br />

provision of services <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure to those areas of the country which are predom<strong>in</strong>antly<br />

populated by the ruler’s tribe. Already <strong>in</strong> 1970, H. Mahdvy, who first advanced the rentier-state<br />

concept, warned that oil states create an impression of prosperity <strong>and</strong> growth whereas <strong>in</strong> reality<br />

‘the mass of the population may rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> a backward state <strong>and</strong> the most important factors for<br />

long-run growth may receive little or not attention at all’ (1970: 437). In Turkmenistan by the end<br />

of the 1990s the heavily subsidized agriculture sector still employed about half of the<br />

economically active population. Students above grade 5 were forced to harvest cotton <strong>and</strong> the<br />

number of students <strong>in</strong> higher education ‘fell from 40,000 <strong>in</strong> 1991 to less than 10,000 by 2004’<br />

(Pomfret 2006: 97-99; see also: Lewis 2008: 80-81). An argument could be made that the quasi-<br />

Sultanistic Turkmen regime (Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> Ochs 2002; Chelabi <strong>and</strong> L<strong>in</strong>z 1998) is pursu<strong>in</strong>g an<br />

active policy of de-diversification of its economy rem<strong>in</strong>iscent of the politics of Mobutu <strong>in</strong> Zaire –<br />

also a rentier state - <strong>in</strong> the 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s which has had tragic long term consequences for the<br />

country (Young <strong>and</strong> Turner 1985; Dunn<strong>in</strong>g 2005).<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, the Turkmen regime has been hostile to all forms of regional co-operation (Oloctt<br />

2005) pursu<strong>in</strong>g a policy of virtual isolation from the outside word. Aga<strong>in</strong> the rentier effect largely<br />

expla<strong>in</strong>s why that is the case. Historically, key energy-rich-states <strong>in</strong> the Middle East – Saudi<br />

Arabia or Kuwait – had been also hostile to regional co-operation. In the context of the Middle<br />

Eastern states it resulted <strong>in</strong> the fiercely negative attitude of Saudi Arabia <strong>and</strong> the Gulf states to the<br />

idea of Pan-Arabism. The issue of artificially drawn colonial border l<strong>in</strong>es does not <strong>in</strong>terest those<br />

elites whose states have been ‘blessed’ with petro-dollars. Hence, the movements which strongly<br />

rely on the symbols which emphasize the unity of all Arabs have been most unwelcome <strong>in</strong> the oilrich<br />

states. 1 Instead, rulers strongly support the movements which use Islamic symbolism. Nazih<br />

Ayubi asserts that an important function of what he calls petro-Islam, which stresses an<br />

<strong>in</strong>terpretation of religion that is both excessively ritualistic <strong>in</strong> style <strong>and</strong> conservative <strong>in</strong> socioeconomic<br />

content, ‘is to keep the oil wealth away from other Arabs’ (2001: 233).<br />

Kazakhstan<br />

Resources-based economies that Turkmen <strong>and</strong> Uzbek rulers <strong>in</strong>herited from the Soviet Union,<br />

coupled with an autocratic regime <strong>and</strong> a lack of human capital to diversify their economies, made<br />

the turn towards rentierism somewhat <strong>in</strong>evitable. Kazakhstan, which today also closely resembles<br />

a rentier economy, started its transformation towards rentierism from a very different po<strong>in</strong>t when<br />

compared to its regional counterparts. The dis<strong>in</strong>tegration of the Soviet Union hit Kazakhstan, a<br />

middle <strong>in</strong>come country <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s, <strong>in</strong>comparably harder than its southern<br />

neighbours s<strong>in</strong>ce the country’s entire <strong>in</strong>dustrial structure was <strong>in</strong>separably <strong>in</strong>tertw<strong>in</strong>ed with that of<br />

Russia. In response to the crisis, the Kazakh regime decided to privatise huge, collaps<strong>in</strong>g<br />

enterprises (to a very mixed effect) <strong>and</strong> itself turned its attention to oil <strong>and</strong> gas. The oil <strong>and</strong> gas<br />

sectors were largely underdeveloped dur<strong>in</strong>g the Soviet era but had a capacity to attract foreign oil<br />

companies <strong>and</strong> much needed FDIs, which they did. The <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> oil prices <strong>in</strong> the 2000s<br />

strengthened the Kazakh dependency on resources <strong>and</strong> led the regime to largely ab<strong>and</strong>on other<br />

sectors of the economy. By the end of the 2000’s, the turn towards rentierism was completed.<br />

As discussed <strong>in</strong> the previous section the relative economic success of Uzbekistan <strong>and</strong><br />

Turkmenistan <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s can be largely expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the <strong>in</strong>terests of the outside<br />

world <strong>in</strong> the commodities they had on sale. Kazakhstan, despite its overwhelm<strong>in</strong>g richness <strong>in</strong> the<br />

natural resource, <strong>in</strong>itially found itself on the other end of the equation. This was largely due to<br />

three reasons a) remote location of many of the deposits, b) <strong>in</strong>adequate or non-exist<strong>in</strong>g transport<br />

l<strong>in</strong>ks to the outside markets <strong>and</strong> c) shift<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terests of the global m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry which <strong>in</strong> the<br />

beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s chose to turn its attention to South American deposits <strong>and</strong> not the post-<br />

Soviet once (Bridge 2004).<br />

1<br />

Other states such as Syria or Libya, which do not have large oil revenues at their disposal, have tried to<br />

<strong>in</strong>spire loyalty among their people through non-state ideologies, i.e. Pan-Arabism.<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

8


Lead<strong>in</strong>g on, <strong>in</strong> the Soviet Union the development of the republic’s extractive <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

followed an enclave type of pattern which mirrored the experience of colonial Africa or n<strong>in</strong>eteen<br />

century South America. Thus, development was regionally concentrated but little, if any,<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> ancillary <strong>in</strong>dustries. The large extractive enterprises were closely l<strong>in</strong>ked to<br />

enterprises <strong>in</strong> other part of the USSR or ‘imperial’ core. It should be added that the same was true<br />

for Kazakhstan’s <strong>in</strong>dustrial economy which ma<strong>in</strong>ly concentrated <strong>in</strong> primary sectors like ferrous<br />

<strong>and</strong> nonferrous metals, fuels, electricity generation, metallurgy <strong>and</strong> mach<strong>in</strong>e build<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong><br />

chemical. The <strong>in</strong>dustrial economy was build around ‘one-company towns’ <strong>in</strong> which production<br />

concentrated on <strong>in</strong>termediate products. Those products had to be sent to factories <strong>in</strong> Russia for<br />

further process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g (Peck 2004: 60-62; Pomfret 2006: 43; see also Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

2000; Olcott 2002). In short, without the Soviet economy there was hardly any Kazakh economy<br />

one could speak off.<br />

The overwhelm<strong>in</strong>g economic problem that Kazakhstan faced <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s<br />

was exacerbated by two additional factors. The enterprises with<strong>in</strong> the border of the newly<br />

<strong>in</strong>dependent Kazakhstan were old <strong>and</strong> suffered from chronic under<strong>in</strong>vestment dur<strong>in</strong>g the late<br />

Soviet era. Thus, the enterprises needed huge funds <strong>in</strong> order to become commercially attractive.<br />

Furthermore, the Russian, German <strong>and</strong> Slavic managerial <strong>and</strong> eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g classes which worked<br />

on major enterprises <strong>in</strong> the north of country began migrat<strong>in</strong>g back to Russian <strong>and</strong> other republics.<br />

In the first decade of <strong>in</strong>dependence almost two million people left Kazakhstan (S<strong>in</strong>nott 2003; Dave<br />

2004).<br />

The response of the Kazakh government to the mount<strong>in</strong>g economical crises, which<br />

followed the collapse <strong>and</strong> dis<strong>in</strong>tegration of the Soviet economy, was to privatise exist<strong>in</strong>g<br />

enterprises <strong>in</strong> the mid-1990s. The Kazakh rul<strong>in</strong>g elite hoped that through privatisation it would be<br />

able to shift responsibility from itself to the private sector for runn<strong>in</strong>g the enterprises <strong>and</strong><br />

ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g social peace <strong>in</strong> ‘one company towns’. Yet, the proposed privatisation did not generate<br />

much <strong>in</strong>terest among mult<strong>in</strong>ationals. Instead the country’s key assets were bought at a very low<br />

price by little known outside companies whose real identity was disguised by company’s off-shore<br />

registration. In the years to come most of them failed to meet their commercial or social<br />

obligations <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stead engaged <strong>in</strong> widespread asset strip<strong>in</strong>g (Ostrowski 2010). The privatisation,<br />

the so-called ‘sale of the century’, deepened the exist<strong>in</strong>g economic <strong>and</strong> social crises <strong>in</strong> the country<br />

(Nazpary 2002) <strong>and</strong> fully opened the doors to crony capitalism which was accompanied by<br />

rampant corruption (Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs 2002, 2003; Furman 2005; Murphy 2006; Dave 2007). As a result,<br />

the Kazakh political system throughout the 1990s began retreat<strong>in</strong>g to a pre-Soviet logic of zhuz<br />

(horde), tribes <strong>and</strong> clans (Schatz 2004).<br />

In the face of collaps<strong>in</strong>g economy <strong>and</strong> grow<strong>in</strong>g social problems the Kazakh rul<strong>in</strong>g elite<br />

turned its full attention to oil <strong>and</strong> gas which were the only two sectors able to attract the <strong>in</strong>terest of<br />

major <strong>in</strong>ternational companies from the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s. In the post-OPEC world,<br />

Kazakhstan, where production on major oil fields began only <strong>in</strong> the 1980s <strong>and</strong> which had an<br />

enormous potential for the future, presented foreign oil companies with a unique opportunit they<br />

were not go<strong>in</strong>g to miss. The regime on its part created <strong>in</strong>stitutional structures – an early version of<br />

the National Oil Company <strong>and</strong> oil laws - which best suited the <strong>in</strong>terests of the outside companies.<br />

The regime further allowed companies to entrench their position <strong>in</strong> post-Soviet Kazakhstan by<br />

sign<strong>in</strong>g a whole host of Production Shar<strong>in</strong>g Agreements which clearly favoured outside companies<br />

(Ostrowski 2010). The bond forged <strong>in</strong> the 1990s between oil companies <strong>and</strong> the Kazakh regimes,<br />

to some extent, mirrors the relationships between Saudi Arabia <strong>and</strong> the western oil companies <strong>in</strong><br />

the 1950s <strong>and</strong> 60s (Vitalis 2007; Yessenova 2007).<br />

The gamble which the Kazakh elites took <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong> the first decade of <strong>in</strong>dependence to<br />

stake their future <strong>and</strong> that of the country at large solely on oil paid off <strong>in</strong> 2000 when a consortium<br />

of western companies discover a Kashagan oilfield, which is the largest oil f<strong>in</strong>d <strong>in</strong> the past 30<br />

years. Accidentally, the discovery was followed by a rapid rise of oil prices on the <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

commodity markets throughout the 2000s f<strong>in</strong>ally br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g much needed revenues (Pomfret 2005:<br />

867-868). This <strong>in</strong> turn allowed the regime to <strong>in</strong>crease social spend<strong>in</strong>g as well as the all important<br />

public sector salaries (Ostrowski 2009: 348-351). What is more the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the revenues also<br />

9<br />

Copyright PSA 2011


gave the regime leverage <strong>in</strong> its relationships with the foreign oil <strong>and</strong> gas companies (Nurmakov<br />

2010; Ostrowski 2010). At the same time, Kazakhstan’s grow<strong>in</strong>g dependency on oil <strong>and</strong> gas<br />

exports meant that the country will have to heavily rely on Russian controlled <strong>in</strong>frastructure for<br />

some time to come. Accord<strong>in</strong>g, to one assessment, around 84 per cent of Kazakhstan’s oil export<br />

still passes through Russia to the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets (ICG 2007: 9; see also Ipek 2007).<br />

Today’s Kazakhstan strongly resembles a classical rentier state 2 . Its full dependency on<br />

commodity markets became all too visible dur<strong>in</strong>g the f<strong>in</strong>ancial crises <strong>in</strong> the late 2000s which <strong>in</strong><br />

Kazakhstan manifested themselves <strong>in</strong> an almost <strong>in</strong>stantaneous collapse of country’s bank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong><br />

build<strong>in</strong>g sectors. The Kazakh political system largely follows a regional pattern of neopatrimonialism<br />

while its economy is shaped <strong>and</strong> dom<strong>in</strong>ated by few oligarchs <strong>and</strong> their cliques<br />

(Kjærnet et al. 2008). However, there are two important differences with Uzbekistan <strong>and</strong><br />

Turkmenistan. Firstly, the Kazakh regime is much more liberal <strong>and</strong> less oppressive than its<br />

regional counterparts,(Olcott 2005) <strong>and</strong> secondly, it recognizes the limits of the politics based on<br />

<strong>in</strong>formal networks. It has been argued that the regime’s long term ambition is to create a political<br />

<strong>and</strong> economical system <strong>in</strong> which formal <strong>in</strong>stitutions would play a much bigger role (Ostrowski<br />

2009). This should facilitate the rise of much more stable political structures which, however, will<br />

not be democratic <strong>in</strong> outlook.<br />

Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan<br />

Kyrgyzstan’s economy, similarly to that of Kazakhstan was badly affected by the collapse of the<br />

Soviet Union, but is not rich <strong>in</strong> exploitable <strong>and</strong> exportable natural resources. Hence, <strong>in</strong> the<br />

beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s it decided to liberalise its economy <strong>and</strong>, at least partly, the political system.<br />

This manoeuvre allowed the post-Soviet regime to obta<strong>in</strong> sufficient foreign aid/rent, from various<br />

Western governments <strong>and</strong> agencies, which helped to smooth the transition from the USSR.<br />

However, this source of rent <strong>in</strong>evitably dried up <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the second decade of <strong>in</strong>dependence the<br />

Kyrgyz state began rely<strong>in</strong>g on the <strong>in</strong>flow of remittances <strong>and</strong> leas<strong>in</strong>g access to territory. The<br />

economy of Tajikistan, the poorest republic <strong>in</strong> the Soviet Union, was almost completely devastated<br />

<strong>and</strong> looted dur<strong>in</strong>g the civil war <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of 1990s. Today, Tajikistan is held together by<br />

remittances sent by labour workers that have been migrat<strong>in</strong>g predom<strong>in</strong>antly to Russia, as well as<br />

foreign aid. Hav<strong>in</strong>g said that, it was also estimated that as much as third of the population depends<br />

on drugs <strong>and</strong> weapons trade.<br />

Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan on the eve of the <strong>in</strong>dependence found themselves <strong>in</strong> a much<br />

more difficult economic situation than any of the other three <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics discussed so<br />

far. This was due to two factors a) both are resources-poor, thus they could not benefit from the<br />

price liberalisation <strong>in</strong> the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the 1990s <strong>in</strong> the same way as Turkmenistan <strong>and</strong> Uzbekistan<br />

did, <strong>and</strong> b) neither of the two had a developed <strong>and</strong> well function<strong>in</strong>g economic base. In the Soviet<br />

Union the Kyrgyz economy was not highly <strong>in</strong>dustrialized <strong>and</strong> ‘much of the <strong>in</strong>dustry that the<br />

republic did have was tightly <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>to the Soviet military-<strong>in</strong>dustrial complex, which left the<br />

republic especially vulnerable after the dissolution of the USSR’ (Pomfret 2006: 71). Tajikistan<br />

was the poorest of the Soviet republics, with 40 per cent of its budget com<strong>in</strong>g from subsidies (ICG<br />

2009: 1).<br />

The response of the Kyrgyz elites to the dis<strong>in</strong>tegration of the Soviet Union, which had far<br />

reach<strong>in</strong>g social <strong>and</strong> economical effects, was to fully embrace the discourse of democracy <strong>and</strong> free<br />

market economy as advocated by IMF <strong>and</strong> World Bank at that time. This <strong>in</strong> turn won the country<br />

the support of ideologically driven major <strong>in</strong>ternational donors <strong>and</strong> some Western governments<br />

(Gleason 2001: 173-174). Both parties between 1992 <strong>and</strong> 2000 poured $1.7 billion <strong>in</strong>to<br />

Kyrgyzstan, a substantial amount of money which greatly aided the Kyrgyz government <strong>in</strong><br />

smooth<strong>in</strong>g out the transition from the Soviet Union (Pomfret 2006: 82-83). Yet, the outside<br />

aid/rent slowly came to an end by early 2000s as donors became <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly disillusioned with<br />

2 Kazakhstan anticipates a total <strong>in</strong>vestment of $52 billion <strong>in</strong> its oil <strong>and</strong> gas sector by the second decade of<br />

2000s (Olcott 2005: 88).<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

10


Kyrgyzstan’s ever more authoritarian political regime <strong>and</strong> the lack of liberal economic reforms<br />

(Lewis 2008: 123-124; Hiro 2009: 296-298).<br />

Tajikistan did not go through the process which is normally understood as a ‘transition’<br />

from Soviet to post-Soviet system. On the eve of <strong>in</strong>dependence, the country collapsed <strong>in</strong>to a civil<br />

war which formally lasted from 1992 to 1997, however, significant political violence cont<strong>in</strong>ued<br />

until 2001 (Heathershaw 2009). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to some accounts, the civil war came about as a result<br />

of the collaps<strong>in</strong>g Soviet economy <strong>in</strong> the late 1980s which was unable to subside Tajikistan any<br />

longer to the same levels as it did <strong>in</strong> the past. Thus, <strong>in</strong> the early 1990s poverty, youth<br />

unemployment, corruption <strong>and</strong> competition for the resources between regionally-def<strong>in</strong>ed groups<br />

were seen as the key reasons for the outbreak of hostilities (Lynch 2001; Ak<strong>in</strong>er 2006). The war<br />

took the lives of 50,000-100,000 people <strong>and</strong> had a devastat<strong>in</strong>g impact on the country’s economy<br />

(Nakaya 2009: 260). By the mid-1990s the <strong>in</strong>dustrial sector, state property <strong>and</strong> bank assets were<br />

looted <strong>and</strong> much of what had any productive value left the country. The physical <strong>in</strong>frastructure was<br />

also largely destroyed. On the eve of the new millennium Tajikistan was ranked among the poorest<br />

countries <strong>in</strong> the world (Pomfret 2006: 65-69).<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce the early 2000s Kyrgyzstan’s <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan’s economies have followed very similar<br />

trajectories. Firstly, both countries overwhelm<strong>in</strong>gly rely overly on labour remittances which<br />

Kyrgyz <strong>and</strong> Tajik workers send home from Russia <strong>and</strong> Kazakhstan. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to some recent<br />

studies ‘Tajikistan has the world’s highest promotion of remittances to GDP. In 2007 remittances<br />

comprised 36% of its GDP, or $1.8 billion, while Kyrgyzstan ranked fourth <strong>in</strong> the world, with 27%<br />

of GDP or $322 million’ (Marat 2009: 7). Secondly, Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan – or rather<br />

country’s rul<strong>in</strong>g elites – greatly rely on <strong>in</strong>come obta<strong>in</strong>ed from leas<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>and</strong> to foreign powers.<br />

Kyrgyzstan is home to both Russian <strong>and</strong> the US military base. The Manas US air base s<strong>in</strong>ce its<br />

creation <strong>in</strong> the early 2000s has become <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly important to the Afghanistan war effort,<br />

someth<strong>in</strong>g that the Kyrgyz elite tried to use to extract more rent through – rather unskilfully –<br />

play<strong>in</strong>g Russian <strong>and</strong> Americans aga<strong>in</strong>st one another (ICG 2010b). Tajikistan <strong>in</strong> 2004 agreed to<br />

become host to a Russian base after the Russian government agreed to write off a large part of the<br />

bilateral debt. Thirdly, both countries are slowly fall<strong>in</strong>g prey to organised crime, which is play<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a grow<strong>in</strong>g role <strong>in</strong> their economical <strong>and</strong> political life (Marat 2006; Kupatadze 2008).<br />

Today, Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan are semi-rentier states. In essence their <strong>in</strong>ternal stability<br />

is <strong>in</strong>directly l<strong>in</strong>ked to the oil <strong>and</strong> gas prices which shape the economic fate of Russia <strong>and</strong><br />

Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> turn determ<strong>in</strong>e the levels of remittances that Kyrgyz <strong>and</strong> Taijk workers will be<br />

able to send home. The place that Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan have <strong>in</strong> a regional economy is largely<br />

the outcome of an <strong>in</strong>significant role that both countries played <strong>in</strong> the Soviet economy which<br />

collapsed <strong>and</strong> left them with a reservoir of cheap, young labour but little more.<br />

The Foreign Policy of <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n (Rentier <strong>and</strong> Semi-Rentier) States<br />

The Kazakh <strong>and</strong> Turkmen autocratic regimes from the first years of <strong>in</strong>dependence attempted to<br />

translate the advantage of hav<strong>in</strong>g substantial natural resources on their territory <strong>in</strong>to consolidat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

their rule <strong>and</strong> their countries sovereignty. The pursuit of greater <strong>in</strong>dependence resulted <strong>in</strong><br />

diametrically opposed foreign policies with Kazakhstan co<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the term of the so-called “multivector”<br />

foreign policy (Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs 2003; Bukkvoll 2004), whereas Turkmenistan opted, uniquely<br />

<strong>in</strong> the post-communist space, for a policy of “Positive Neutrality” (Anceschi 2009). In both cases<br />

post-<strong>in</strong>dependence foreign policy became an important part of the state ideology <strong>and</strong> aided rulers<br />

<strong>in</strong> strengthen<strong>in</strong>g their grip on power. However, <strong>in</strong> neither of the cases have they led to limit<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

countries’ dependency on Russia, quite to the contrary. The grow<strong>in</strong>g reliance of both states on oil<br />

<strong>and</strong> gas resources, re<strong>in</strong>forced by a lack of economic diversification, strengthens Kazakh <strong>and</strong><br />

Turkmen dependency on the Russian controlled pipel<strong>in</strong>e system, a dependency which both rul<strong>in</strong>g<br />

regimes found extremely complicated to overcome for various <strong>in</strong>ternal <strong>and</strong> external reasons. Yet, it<br />

has to be said, that this relationship of dependency <strong>in</strong> the case of Turkmenistan has been partly<br />

balanced by grow<strong>in</strong>g Russian reliance on Turkmen gas (K<strong>and</strong>iyoti 2008).<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

11


In the case of Kazakhstan, the reliance on the Russian controlled <strong>in</strong>frastructure re<strong>in</strong>forced<br />

by geographical proximity <strong>and</strong> an ethnic Russian m<strong>in</strong>ority liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan, has led to the<br />

decision on parts of the rul<strong>in</strong>g regime to largely follow the Russian lead on the <strong>in</strong>ternational stage<br />

(Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs 2005; Dave 2007). Thus, the Kazakh regime pursues the long term goal of not<br />

antagoniz<strong>in</strong>g Russia but to rather grow <strong>in</strong> strength next to it, at least for the time be<strong>in</strong>g. Rather<br />

tell<strong>in</strong>gly, Kazakhstan only began consolidat<strong>in</strong>g its relationships with Ch<strong>in</strong>a <strong>in</strong> the mid-2000s after<br />

Ch<strong>in</strong>ese-Russian rapprochement, whereas the <strong>in</strong>fluence of Western oil companies has been largely<br />

limited to oil enclaves. Turkmenistan, contrary to Kazakhstan engaged on the one h<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> a series<br />

of disputes concern<strong>in</strong>g the price of gas sold to Russia <strong>and</strong> Ukra<strong>in</strong>e through Russian controlled<br />

pipel<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>and</strong>, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, chose to pursue a policy of virtual isolation from the outside<br />

world. The change at the apex of power of the rul<strong>in</strong>g regime <strong>in</strong> the second half of 2000s was<br />

marked by a cont<strong>in</strong>uation of foreign policy rather than a mean<strong>in</strong>gful shift towards greater openness<br />

(Anceschi 2008).<br />

The situation has been very different <strong>in</strong> the case of Uzbekistan which overwhelm<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

relies on cotton <strong>and</strong> gold, <strong>and</strong> whose exports to <strong>in</strong>ternational markets do not depend to the same<br />

extent as <strong>in</strong> the case of Turkmenistan <strong>and</strong> Kazakhstan on Russian controlled <strong>in</strong>frastructure. This<br />

situation has allowed the Uzbek regime to manoeuvre rather freely between Russia, US, European<br />

states as well as Ch<strong>in</strong>a (Spechler <strong>and</strong> Spechler 2009). This highly flexible foreign policy leads not<br />

only to the consolidation of the rul<strong>in</strong>g regime <strong>and</strong> suppression of <strong>in</strong>ternal dissent, but also greatly<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases Uzbek sovereignty. Thus, when compared to Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong> Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan<br />

emerges as a unique case <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> s<strong>in</strong>ce it is the only state that managed to end its direct<br />

dependency on Russia. At the same time, Uzbek <strong>in</strong>dependent foreign policy is built on very weak<br />

foundations. Over the last two decades, the rul<strong>in</strong>g regime failed to diversify the country’s economy<br />

away from cotton, the prices of which are highly unstable, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stead became <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly reliant<br />

on <strong>in</strong>direct taxation of labour remittances by different levels of the state bureaucracy. Hence, the<br />

ma<strong>in</strong>tenance of the Uzbek version of “multi-vector” foreign policy <strong>and</strong> state sovereignty is a<br />

serious challenge to the authoritarian regime.<br />

In recent years, Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan, similarly to Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong> Uzbekistan also<br />

declared the <strong>in</strong>tention of pursu<strong>in</strong>g a “multi-vector” foreign policy. However, while <strong>in</strong> the Uzbek<br />

context the multi-vector policy has been framed as an outcome of strategic reposition<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

Kazakhstan as an expression of the regime’s <strong>in</strong>spiration to achieve full sovereignty, <strong>in</strong> the Kyrgyz<br />

<strong>and</strong> Tajik cases the policy of “multi-vector” policy has been rather a reflection of a position <strong>in</strong><br />

which those states found themselves on the regional “chessboard” (Spechler 2008). In both cases,<br />

the almost full dependency of aid <strong>and</strong> labour remittances significantly narrows a leader’s room to<br />

manoeuvre <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>evitably undercuts these states’ sovereignty.<br />

Conclusion: Rent <strong>and</strong> <strong>Sovereignty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong><br />

Twenty years after the fall of the Soviet Union <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n republics are still shaped by the<br />

Soviet policies the legacy of which has been chiefly upheld <strong>and</strong> re<strong>in</strong>forced by the neo-liberal<br />

project. In the new post-Soviet reality the rulers of the three <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n states Turkmenistan,<br />

Uzbekistan <strong>and</strong> Kazakhstan largely embraced the role that was envisioned for their republics by<br />

the Soviet planners. The privatisation of state assets by the elites <strong>in</strong> the 1990s has guaranteed them<br />

access to rent, the constant flow of which quickly became their ma<strong>in</strong> preoccupation. As a result of<br />

this, an <strong>in</strong>terest of the rul<strong>in</strong>g cliques <strong>in</strong> state sovereignty has been directly <strong>and</strong> unbreakably l<strong>in</strong>ked<br />

to the issue of rent <strong>and</strong> its control. That is to say that whoever guarantees a steady flow of rent is<br />

also seen as a strategic partner <strong>and</strong> a best guarantor of a country’s sovereignty. The situation is<br />

largely the same <strong>in</strong> Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan.<br />

A political reality <strong>in</strong> which private <strong>in</strong>terests are a key political <strong>and</strong> economical determ<strong>in</strong>ant<br />

is a product of an elite which was shaped by imperial project <strong>and</strong> accepted its values. In this sense<br />

<strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> follows a path travelled by other post-colonial resources-rich states (Gammer 2000).<br />

And if history can tell us anyth<strong>in</strong>g we can safely concluded that rent will chiefly determ<strong>in</strong>e the<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

12


political calculations of the <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n rulers for the time to come. This <strong>in</strong> turn will most likely<br />

have a negative impact on these republics’ sovereignty.<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

13


Bibliography:<br />

Addleton, Jonathan. 1992. Underm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the Centre. The Gulf Migration <strong>and</strong> Pakistan, Karachi:<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

Ak<strong>in</strong>er, Shir<strong>in</strong>. 2006. ‘Conflict <strong>and</strong> Post-Conflict Tajikistan: A Case Study’, In Tschirgi, N <strong>and</strong><br />

Manc<strong>in</strong>i, F, (ed.), Impacts of Security <strong>and</strong> Development Policies <strong>in</strong> Achiev<strong>in</strong>g Susta<strong>in</strong>able<br />

Peace. New York: International Peace Academy.<br />

Anceschi, Luca. 2008. ‘Analyz<strong>in</strong>g Turkmen Foreign Policy <strong>in</strong> the Berdymuhammedov Era.’ Ch<strong>in</strong>a<br />

<strong>and</strong> Euroasia Forum Quarterly, Volume 6, No. 4, p. 35-48.<br />

Anceschi, Luca. 2009. Turkmenistan’s Foreign Policy. Positive Neutrality <strong>and</strong> the Consolidation<br />

of the Turkmen regime. London: Routledge.<br />

Anderson, Lisa. 1987. ‘The State <strong>in</strong> the Middle East <strong>and</strong> North Africa.’ Comparative Politics, 20<br />

(1): October, pp. 1–18.<br />

Ayubi, Nazih. 2001. Over-Stat<strong>in</strong>g the Arab State. Politics <strong>and</strong> Society <strong>in</strong> Middle East. London:<br />

I.B. Tauris Publishers.<br />

Bratton, Michael <strong>and</strong> Nicolas van de Walle. 1994. ‘Neopatrimonial Regimes <strong>and</strong> Political<br />

Transitions <strong>in</strong> Africa.’ World Politics, 46 (4): (Jul. 1994), pp. 453–489.<br />

Bratton, Michael <strong>and</strong> Nicolas van de Walle. 1997. Democratic Experiments <strong>in</strong> Africa. Regime<br />

Transitions <strong>in</strong> Comparative Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.<br />

Beblawi, Hazem. 1987. ‘The Rentier State <strong>in</strong> the Arab World.’ In Hazem Beblawi <strong>and</strong> Giacomo<br />

Luciani (eds.), The Rentier State: Volume II. London: Croom Helm.<br />

Bridge, Gav<strong>in</strong>. 2004. ‘Mapp<strong>in</strong>g the Bonanza: Geographies of M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Investment <strong>in</strong> an Era of<br />

Neoliberal Reform.’ The Professional Geographer, 56(3):406–421.<br />

Brynen, Rex. 1992. ‘Economic Crisis <strong>and</strong> Post-Rentier Democratization <strong>in</strong> the Arab World: The<br />

Case of Jordan.’ Canadian Journal of Political Science, 25 (1): March, pp. 69–97<br />

Bukkvoll, Tor. 2004. ‘Astana’s Privatised Independence: Private <strong>and</strong> National Interests <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Foreign Policy of Nursultan Nazarbayev’, Nationalities Papers, 32 (3): 631-650.<br />

Chaudhry, Kiren A. 1994. ‘Economic Liberalization <strong>and</strong> the L<strong>in</strong>eages of the Rentier State.’<br />

Comparative Politics. Volume 27, Issue 1, October, pp. 1-25.<br />

Chaudhry, Kiren A. 1989. ‘The Price of Wealth: Bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong> State <strong>in</strong> Labour Remittance <strong>and</strong> Oil<br />

Economies.’ International Organisation, 43 (1): W<strong>in</strong>ter, pp. 101–145.<br />

Chelabi, H.E. <strong>and</strong> Juan L<strong>in</strong>z. (eds.). 1998. Sultanistic Regimes. The Johns Hopk<strong>in</strong>s University<br />

Press: Baltimore.<br />

Clark, John. 1997. ‘Petro-Politics <strong>in</strong> Congo.’ Journal of Democracy, 8 (3), pp. 62–76.<br />

Clapham, Christopher. 1996. Africa <strong>and</strong> the International System. The Politics of State Survival.<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

14


Coll<strong>in</strong>s, Kathleen. 2006. Clan Politics <strong>and</strong> Regime Transition <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. New York:<br />

Cambridge University Press.<br />

Coll<strong>in</strong>s, Kathleen. 2009. ‘Economic <strong>and</strong> Security Regionalism among Patrimonial Authoritarian<br />

Regimes: The Case of <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>.’ Europe-<strong>Asia</strong> Studies, Vol. 61, No. 2, March, 249-<br />

281.<br />

Crystal, Jill. 1990. Oil <strong>and</strong> Politics <strong>in</strong> the Gulf. Rulers <strong>and</strong> Merchants <strong>in</strong> Kuwait <strong>and</strong> Qatar.<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs, Sally N. 2000. Kazakhstan: Center-Periphery Relations, London: The Royal Institute<br />

of International Affairs.<br />

Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs, Sally N. 2002. ‘Kazakhstan: An Uneasy Relationship – Power <strong>and</strong> Authority <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Nazarbaev regime’, In Sally N. Cumm<strong>in</strong>g (ed.) Power <strong>and</strong> Change <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>,<br />

London: Routledge.<br />

Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs, Sally <strong>and</strong> M. Ochs. 2002. ‘Turkmenistan-Saparmurat Niyazov’s <strong>in</strong>glorious isolation.’<br />

In Sally N. Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs (ed.), Power <strong>and</strong> Change <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. London: Routledge.<br />

Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs, Sally N. 2003. ‘Independent Kazakhstan: Manag<strong>in</strong>g Heterogeneity’, In Sally N.<br />

Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs (ed.) Oil, Transition <strong>and</strong> Security <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>, London: RoutledgeCurzon.<br />

Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs, Sally N. 2003. ‘Eurasian Bridge or Murky Waters Between East <strong>and</strong> West? Ideas,<br />

Identity <strong>and</strong> Output <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan’s Foreign Policy’, Journal of Communist Studies <strong>and</strong><br />

Transition Politics, 19 (3): September.<br />

Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs, Sally N. 2005. Kazakhstan: Power <strong>and</strong> the Elite, London: I.B. Tauris.<br />

Dave, Bhavna. 2004. ‘Entitlement through Number: Nationality <strong>and</strong> Language Categories <strong>in</strong> the<br />

First Post-Soviet Census of Kazakhstan’, Nations <strong>and</strong> Nationalism, 10 (4): 439–459.<br />

Dave, Bhavna. 2007. Kazakhstan: Ethnicity, Language <strong>and</strong> Power, London: Routledge.<br />

Dunn<strong>in</strong>g, Thad. 2005. ‘Resource Dependence, Economic Performance, <strong>and</strong> Political Stability’,<br />

Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49 (4): 451–482.<br />

Ebel, Robert. 2000. ‘Introduction’, <strong>in</strong> Robert Ebel (ed.) Caspian Energy Resources. Implications<br />

for the Arab Gulf, Abu Dhabi: The Emirates Center for Strategic Studies <strong>and</strong> Research.<br />

Entelis, John. 1996. ‘The Emergence of Civil Society <strong>in</strong> Algeria.’ In Augustus Richard Norton<br />

(ed.), Civil Society <strong>in</strong> the Middle East: Volume Two. Leiden: E.J. Brill.<br />

Franke, Anja, Andrea Gawrich <strong>and</strong> Gurban Alakbarov. 2009. ‘Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong> Azerbaijan as Post-<br />

Soviet Rentier States: Resource Incomes <strong>and</strong> Autocracy as a Double ‘Curse’ <strong>in</strong> Post-<br />

Soviet Regimes,’ Europe-<strong>Asia</strong> Studies, 61 (2): 109–140.<br />

Frynas, Jędrzej G. 2004. ‘The Oil Boom <strong>in</strong> Equatorial Gu<strong>in</strong>ea.’ African Affairs, 103 (413):<br />

October, pp. 527–546.<br />

Furman, Dimitrii. 2005. ‘The Regime <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan’, In Boris Rummer (ed.) <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> at the<br />

End of the Transition, New York: M.E. Sharpe.<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

15


Gammer, M. 2000. ‘Post-Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> <strong>and</strong> post-colonial Francophone Africa: Some<br />

associations.’ Middle Eastern Studies, 36 (2): 124-49.<br />

Gleason, Gregory. 1991. ‘The Political Economy of <strong>Dependency</strong> under Socialism: The <strong>Asia</strong>n<br />

Republics <strong>in</strong> the USSR’, Studies <strong>in</strong> Comparative Communism, 24 (4): 335–353.<br />

Gleason, Gregory. 2001. ‘Foreign Policy <strong>and</strong> Domestic Reform <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>’, <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n<br />

Survey, 20(2), 167-182.<br />

Gleason, Gregory. 2003. Markets <strong>and</strong> Politics <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. Structural Reform <strong>and</strong> Political<br />

Change. London: Routledge.<br />

Heathershaw, John. 2009. Post-Conflict Tajikistan. The politics of peacebuild<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> the<br />

emergence of legitimate order. Routledge.<br />

H<strong>in</strong>nebusch, Raymond. 2000. ‘Liberalization without Democratization <strong>in</strong> ‘Post-populist’<br />

Authoritarian States.’ In Nils Butenschon, Uri Davis <strong>and</strong> Manuel Hassassian (eds),<br />

Citizenship <strong>and</strong> State <strong>in</strong> the Middle East. Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press.<br />

H<strong>in</strong>nebusch, Raymond. 2003. The International Politics of the Middle East. Manchester:<br />

Manchester University Press.<br />

H<strong>in</strong>nebusch, Raymond. 2006. ‘Authoritarian Persistence, Democratization Theory <strong>and</strong> the Middle<br />

East: An Overview <strong>and</strong> Critique.’ Democratization, Vol. 13, No. 3, pp. 373-395.<br />

Ilkhamov, Alisher. 2007. ‘Neopatrimonialism, <strong>in</strong>terest groups <strong>and</strong> patronage networks: the<br />

impasses of the governance system <strong>in</strong> Uzbekistan.’ <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n Survey, Volume 26,<br />

Issue 1 March, pages 65 – 84.<br />

International Crisis Group (ICG). 2005. ‘The Curse of Cotton: <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>’s Destructive<br />

Monoculture’, <strong>Asia</strong> Report No. 93, 28 February.<br />

International Crisis Group (ICG). 2007. ‘<strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>’s Energy Risks’, <strong>Asia</strong> Report, No. 133-24,<br />

May 2007.<br />

International Crisis Group (ICG). 2009. ‘Tajikistan: On the Road to Failure’, <strong>Asia</strong> Report, No.<br />

162, 12 February 2009.<br />

International Crisis Group (ICG). 2010a. ‘<strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>: Migrants <strong>and</strong> the Economic Crisis’, <strong>Asia</strong><br />

Report, No. 183, 5 January.<br />

International Crisis Group (ICG). 2010b. ‘Kyrgyzstan: A Hollow Regime Collapses’, <strong>Asia</strong><br />

Brief<strong>in</strong>g, No 102, 27 April.<br />

Ipek, P<strong>in</strong>ar. 2007. ‘The Role of Oil <strong>and</strong> Gas <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan’s Foreign Policy: Look<strong>in</strong>g East or<br />

West?’ Europe-<strong>Asia</strong> Studies, Vol. 59, No. 7, November, 1179-1199.<br />

Ishiyama, John. 2002. ‘Neopatrimonialism <strong>and</strong> the prospects for democratization <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Central</strong><br />

<strong>Asia</strong>n republic.’ In Sally N. Cumm<strong>in</strong>gs (ed.), Power <strong>and</strong> Change <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>.<br />

London: Routledge.<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

16


Kamp, Marianne. 2004. ‘Between Woman <strong>and</strong> the State: Mahalla Committee <strong>and</strong> Social Welfare<br />

<strong>in</strong> Uzbekistan.’ In Paul<strong>in</strong>e Jones Luong (ed.), The Transformation of <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. State<br />

<strong>and</strong> Societies from Soviet Rule to Independence. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.<br />

K<strong>and</strong>iyoti, Deniz. 2002. ‘Post-Colonialism Compared: Potentials <strong>and</strong> Limitations <strong>in</strong> the Middle<br />

East <strong>and</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>’, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 34, 279–297.<br />

K<strong>and</strong>iyoti, Rafael. 2008. Pipel<strong>in</strong>es: Flow<strong>in</strong>g Oil <strong>and</strong> Crude Politics, London: I.B. Tauris.<br />

Karl, Terry L. 1997. The Paradox of Plenty. Oil Booms <strong>and</strong> Petro-States. Berkeley: University Of<br />

California Press.<br />

Karl, Terry L. 2007. ‘Ensur<strong>in</strong>g Fairness: The Case for a Transparent Fiscal Social Contract.’ In<br />

Macartan Humphreys, Jeffrey D. Sachs, Joseph E. Stiglitz (eds.), Escap<strong>in</strong>g the Resource<br />

Curse. New York: Columbia University Press.<br />

Khalid, Adeeb. 2007. Islam after Communism, Berkeley: University of California Press.<br />

Kim, Younkyoo. 2003. The Resources Curse <strong>in</strong> a Post-Communist Regime. Russian Comparative<br />

Prospective. Hants.: Ashgate.<br />

Kjærnet, Heidi; Dosym Satpaev <strong>and</strong> St<strong>in</strong>a Torjesen. 2008. ‘Big Bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong> High-level Politics <strong>in</strong><br />

Kazakhstan: An Everlast<strong>in</strong>g Symbiosis?’, Ch<strong>in</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Eurasia Forum Quarterly, 6 :1;<br />

pp.95–107.<br />

Kupatadze, Alex<strong>and</strong>er. 2008. ‘Organized Crime before <strong>and</strong> after Tulip Revolution: chang<strong>in</strong>g<br />

dynamics of upperworld-underworld networks’ <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n Survey, 27:3.<br />

Kuru, Ahmet. 2002. ‘The Rentier State Model <strong>and</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n Studies: The Turkmen Case.’<br />

Alternatives: Turkish Journal of International Relations, 1 (1): Spr<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Le Billon, Philippe. 2001. ‘The Political Ecology of War: Natural Resources <strong>and</strong> Armed<br />

Conflicts’, Political Geography, 20: 561–584.<br />

Lewis, David. 2008. The Temptations of Tyranny <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. London: Hurst.<br />

Liebowitz, Ronald. 1987. ‘Soviet Investment Strategy: A Further Test of the ‘Equalization<br />

Hypothesis’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 77 (3): 396–407.<br />

Le V<strong>in</strong>e, Victor. 1980. ‘African Patrimonial Regimes <strong>in</strong> Comparative Perspective.’ The Journal of<br />

Modern African Studies, 18 (4), pp. 657–673.<br />

Lub<strong>in</strong>, Nancy. 1984. Labour <strong>and</strong> Nationality <strong>in</strong> Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>, New Jersey: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton<br />

University Press.<br />

Luciani, Giacomo. 1987. ‘Allocation vs. Production States.’ In Hazem Beblawi <strong>and</strong> Giacomo<br />

Luciani (eds.), The Rentier State: Volume II. London: Croom Helm.<br />

Luong, Jones Paul<strong>in</strong>e. 2000. ‘The ‘Use <strong>and</strong> Abuse’ of Russia’s Energy Resources: Implications for<br />

State-Society Relations.’ In Valerie Sperl<strong>in</strong>g (ed.), Build<strong>in</strong>g The Russian State:<br />

Institutional Crisis <strong>and</strong> the Quest for Democratic Governance. Colorado: Westview<br />

Press.<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

17


Luong, Jones Paul<strong>in</strong>e. 2002. Institutional Change <strong>and</strong> Political Cont<strong>in</strong>uity <strong>in</strong> Post-Soviet <strong>Central</strong><br />

<strong>Asia</strong>. Power, Perceptions, <strong>and</strong> Pacts, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Luong, Jones Paul<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> We<strong>in</strong>thal, Erika. 2001. ‘Prelude to The Resource Curse: Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Oil<br />

And Gas Development Strategies In The Soviet Successor States And Beyond’,<br />

Comparative Political Studies, 34 (4): 367–399.<br />

Lynch, Dov. 2001. ‘The Tajik Civil War <strong>and</strong> Peace Process’, Civil Wars 4(4), pp. 49-72.<br />

Mahdavy, H. 1970. ‘The Patters <strong>and</strong> Problems of Economic Development <strong>in</strong> Rentier States: the<br />

Case of Iran.’ In M.A. Cook (ed.), Studies <strong>in</strong> The Economic History of The Middle East.<br />

London: Oxford University Press.<br />

Marat, Erica. 2006. ‘The State-Crime Nexus <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>: State Weakness, Organized Crime,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Corruption <strong>in</strong> Kyrgyzstan <strong>and</strong> Tajikistan.’ <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>-Caucasus Institute <strong>and</strong> Silk<br />

Road Studies Program, October.<br />

Marat, Erica. 2009. ‘Labour Migration <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>: Implication of the Global Economic<br />

Crisis.’ <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>-Caucasus Institute <strong>and</strong> Silk Road Studies Program, May.<br />

Murphy, Jonathan. 2006. ‘Illusory Transition? Elite Reconstitution <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan, 1989-2002’,<br />

Europe-<strong>Asia</strong> Studies, 58 (4): 523–554.<br />

Nakaya, Sumie. 2009. ‘Aid <strong>and</strong> transition from a war economy to an oligarchy <strong>in</strong> post-war<br />

Tajikistan’, <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n Survey, 28 (3), September, pp. 259-273.<br />

Nazpary, Joma. 2002. Post-Soviet Chaos: Violence <strong>and</strong> Dispossession <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan, London:<br />

Pluto Press.<br />

Noreng, Oyste<strong>in</strong>. 2002. Crude Power: Politics <strong>and</strong> the Oil Market. London: I.B. Tauris.<br />

Nurmakov, Adil. 2010. ‘Resources nationalism <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan’s petroleum sector: curse or<br />

bless<strong>in</strong>g?’ In Indra Overl<strong>and</strong>, Heidi Kjaernet <strong>and</strong> Andrea Kendall-Taylor (ed.), Caspian<br />

Energy Politics: Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong> Turkmenistan. New York: Routledge.<br />

Odum, Just<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> Erica Johnson. 2004. ‘The State of Physical Infrastructure <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>:<br />

Developments <strong>in</strong> Transport, Water, Energy, <strong>and</strong> Telecommunications.’ NBR Analysis 15.5.<br />

Okruhlik, Gwenn. 1999. ‘Rentier Wealth, Unruly Law, <strong>and</strong> the Rise of Opposition. The Political<br />

Economy of Oil States.’ Comparative Politics, 31 (3): April, pp. 295–315.<br />

Olcott, Martha B. 2002. Kazakhstan. Unfulfilled Promises, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton DC: Carnegie Endowment<br />

for International Peace.<br />

Olcott, Martha B. 2005. <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>’s Second Chance, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton DC: Carnegie Endowment for<br />

International Peace.<br />

Omgba, Desire Luc. 2009. ‘On the Duration of Political Power <strong>in</strong> Africa. The Role of Oil Rents.’<br />

Comparative Political Studies, 42 (3): March, pp. 416-436.<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

18


Ostrowski, Wojciech. 2009. ‘The legacy of the ‘coloured revolutions’: the case of Kazakhstan.’<br />

Journal of Communist Studies <strong>and</strong> Transition Politics, Vol.25, Nos.2–3, June–September,<br />

pp. 347–368<br />

Ostrowski, Wojciech. 2010. Politics <strong>and</strong> Oil <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan. London: Routledge.<br />

Ozornoy, Gennady. 1991. ‘Some Issues of Regional Inequality <strong>in</strong> the USSR under Gorbachev’,<br />

Regional Studies, 25 (5): 381–393.<br />

Peck, Anne E. 2004. Economic Development <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan. The Role of Large Enterprises <strong>and</strong><br />

Foreign Investment, London: RoutledgeCurzon.<br />

Pomfret, Richard. 2005. ‘Kazakhstan’s Economy S<strong>in</strong>ce Independence: Does the Oil Boom Offer a<br />

Second Chance for Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development?’, Europe–<strong>Asia</strong> Studies, 57 (6): 859-976.<br />

Pomfret, Richard. 2006. The <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n Economies s<strong>in</strong>ce Independence. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton<br />

University Press.<br />

Roeder, Philip. 1991. ‘Soviet Federalism <strong>and</strong> Ethnic Mobilisation’, World Politics, 43 (2): 196–<br />

232.<br />

Rotberg, Robert. 2004. ‘The Failure <strong>and</strong> Collapse of Nation-States: Breakdown, Prevention, <strong>and</strong><br />

Repair.’ In Robert Rotberg (ed.), When States Fail: Causes <strong>and</strong> Consequences. Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton:<br />

Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University Press.<br />

Stevens, Paul. 2008. ‘Oil Wars: Resource Nationalism <strong>and</strong> the Middle East.’ In Philip Andrews-<br />

Speed (ed.), International Competition for Resources. The role of law, the state <strong>and</strong> of<br />

markets. Dundee: Dundee University Press.<br />

Ross, Michael. 2001. ‘Does Oil H<strong>in</strong>der Democracy?’ World Politics, Vol. 53, No. 3 (Apr.), pp.<br />

325-361.<br />

Ross, Michael . 1999. ‘The Political Economy of the Resource Curse,’ World Politics 51 (2,<br />

January), 297-322.<br />

Rumer, Boris Z. 1989. Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. ‘A tragic experiment’, Boston: Unw<strong>in</strong> Hyman.<br />

Rumer, Eugene. ‘The U.S. <strong>in</strong>terests <strong>and</strong> role <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> after K2,’ The Wash<strong>in</strong>gton Quarterly,<br />

29 (3): 141-154.<br />

Schatz, Edward. 2004. Modern Clan Politics. The Power of ‘Blood’ <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan <strong>and</strong> Beyond,<br />

Seattle: University of Wash<strong>in</strong>gton Press.<br />

Shambayati, Hootan. 1994. ‘The Rentier State, Interest Groups, <strong>and</strong> the Paradox of Autonomy:<br />

State <strong>and</strong> Bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> Turkey <strong>and</strong> Iran.’ Comparative Politics, 26 (3): April, pp. 307–331.<br />

Shaxson, Nicholas. 2007. Poisoned Wells: The Dirty Politics of African Oil. London: Palgrave.<br />

Skocpol, Theda. 1982. ‘Rentier State <strong>and</strong> Shi’a Islam <strong>in</strong> the Iranian Revolution.’ Theory <strong>and</strong><br />

Society, 11 May, pp. 293–300.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>nott, Peter. 2003. ‘Population Politics <strong>in</strong> Kazakhstan’, Journal of International Affairs, 56 (2):<br />

103-115.<br />

19<br />

Copyright PSA 2011


Smith, Benjam<strong>in</strong>. 2004. ‘Oil Wealth <strong>and</strong> Regime Survival <strong>in</strong> the Develop<strong>in</strong>g World, 1960-1999.’<br />

American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 48, No. 2 (Apr., 2004), pp. 232-246.<br />

Soares de Oliveira, Ricardo. 2007. Oil <strong>and</strong> Politics <strong>in</strong> the Gulf of Gu<strong>in</strong>ea. New York: Columbia<br />

University Press.<br />

Spechler, D<strong>in</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Mart<strong>in</strong> Spechler. 2009. ‘Uzbekistan among the great powers.’ Communist <strong>and</strong><br />

Post-Communist Studies, 42, 353-373.<br />

Spechler, Mart<strong>in</strong>. 2008. The Political Economy of Reform <strong>in</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>, London: Routledge.<br />

Spoor, Max. 1993. ‘Transition to Market Economies <strong>in</strong> Former Soviet <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>: <strong>Dependency</strong>,<br />

Cotton <strong>and</strong> Water.’ Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper Series No, 160, September.<br />

Stevens, Paul. 2008. ‘Oil Wars: Resource Nationalism <strong>and</strong> the Middle East.’ In Philip Andrews-<br />

Speed (ed.), International Competition for Resources. The role of law, the state <strong>and</strong> of<br />

markets. Dundee: Dundee University Press.<br />

Vaksberg, Arkady. 1991. The Soviet Mafia. New York: St. Mart<strong>in</strong>’s Press.<br />

Wood, Tony. 2007. ‘Contours of the Put<strong>in</strong> Era.’ New Left Review, 44 (Mar/Apr), pp. 53–71.<br />

Yates, Douglas. 1996. The Rentier State <strong>in</strong> Africa. Oil Rent <strong>Dependency</strong> <strong>and</strong> Neocolonialism <strong>in</strong><br />

the Republic of Gabon. Trenton: Africa World Press, Inc.<br />

Yessenova, Saulesh. 2007. ‘Tengiz Crude: a View from Below.’ In Boris Najman, Richard<br />

Pomfret, Gaël Raball<strong>and</strong> (eds.), The Economics <strong>and</strong> Politics of Oil <strong>in</strong> the Caspian Bas<strong>in</strong>:<br />

The Redistribution of Oil Revenues <strong>in</strong> Azerbaijan <strong>and</strong> <strong>Central</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. London: Routledge.<br />

Young, Craford <strong>and</strong> Thomas Turner. (1985). The Rise <strong>and</strong> Decl<strong>in</strong>e of the Zairian State. Madison:<br />

University of Wiscons<strong>in</strong> Press.<br />

Vitalis, Robert. 2007. America’s K<strong>in</strong>gdom: Mythmak<strong>in</strong>g on the Saudi Frontier. Stanford. CA:<br />

Stanford University Press.<br />

Copyright PSA 2011<br />

20


Copyright PSA 2011<br />

21

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!