21.03.2013 Views

NEF-Southampton-Positive-Money-ICB-Submission

NEF-Southampton-Positive-Money-ICB-Submission

NEF-Southampton-Positive-Money-ICB-Submission

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

educing the income and purchasing power of the very people who rescued the economy by borrowing when<br />

interest rates were low.<br />

In contrast, full-­‐reserve banking offers the Bank of England and the Monetary Policy CommiOee a way of<br />

directly increasing or decreasing the money supply, and therefore avoids this ‘manic-­‐depressive’<br />

management of the economy. It also avoids the need to ship interest rates that affect every exisGng borrower<br />

simply to influence the small group of people who are considering increasing their borrowing at any<br />

parGcular moment in Gme. Under full-­‐reserve banking, interest rates can be set by supply and demand<br />

through the markets, with the banks acGng as intermediaries between savers and borrowers.<br />

Re-­‐DistribuPon Of Wealth Upwards & Inwards<br />

Because the enGre money supply is created as a debt by commercial banks, in effect interest must be paid to<br />

the banks on every single pound of bank deposits that exists in the economy. A part of this interest is<br />

redistributed back to depositors via interest on savings accounts, etc., but by far the bulk of it is distributed to<br />

the workers of the banks, via salaries and bonuses. This creates three re-­‐distribuGon effects:<br />

1. From the Poor to the Rich:<br />

All money is created as debt by the banking system. This ships the ‘baseline’ of poverty down to zero<br />

or negaGve, rather than a low but posiGve bank balance. Because it is those on below-­‐average<br />

incomes that end up with much of the debt, they end up paying interest to the banking sector, in<br />

effect meaning that the poor subsidise the middle class or rich.<br />

2. From the ‘Real’ Economy to the Financial Sector<br />

Businesses are also in a similar situaGon. The ‘real’ (non-­‐financial), producGve economy needs money<br />

to funcGon, but because all money is created as debt, that sector will also end up paying interest to<br />

the banks. This means that real-­‐economy businesses – shops, offices, factories, etc. – end up<br />

subsidising the banking sector.<br />

3. From the Rest of the UK to the City of London and the South East<br />

Because this debt-­‐based system returns money to the banking sector, and the bulk of banking sector<br />

salary payments are concentrated within the City of London, this means that there is a transfer of<br />

income from the rest of the UK to the City of London and the South-­‐East.<br />

All of these ‘re-­‐distribuGon effects’ are inherent to the system and will conGnue year aper year as long as the<br />

money supply is issued by commercial banks as debt, via fracGonal reserve banking. Further research needs<br />

to be done, but it is very possible that the ‘upwards-­‐and-­‐inwards’ redistribuGon of income caused by this<br />

system of issuing money cancels out any downwards-­‐and-­‐outwards redistribuGon of income through the<br />

welfare state. Looked at another way, the welfare state may only be necessary because of the design of the<br />

banking system, and could be significantly scaled back if the method of creaGng money was reformed. This<br />

should offer a significant opportunity to improve the fiscal posiGon of the government.<br />

The Need for Deposit Insurance<br />

Under fracGonal reserve banking, a bank will never have sufficient money at any one Gme to repay all its<br />

demand liabiliGes (instant access accounts) simultaneously. This means that a ‘run on the bank’ can very<br />

23

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!