03.06.2013 Views

The Dutch Tulip Mania - Maurits van der Veen

The Dutch Tulip Mania - Maurits van der Veen

The Dutch Tulip Mania - Maurits van der Veen

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong>: <strong>The</strong> Social Politics of a Financial Bubble<br />

Abstract<br />

A. <strong>Maurits</strong> <strong>van</strong> <strong>der</strong> <strong>Veen</strong><br />

Assistant Professor<br />

Department of International Affairs<br />

University of Georgia<br />

March 2009<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> tulip mania of 1636-1637 is widely seen as the first recorded instance of a<br />

financial bubble. In recent years, however, economists have argued that prices offered<br />

and paid for tulip bulbs, while extremely high, nevertheless reflected un<strong>der</strong>lying<br />

economic fundamentals. If valid, such claims imply that the tulip mania cannot be<br />

consi<strong>der</strong>ed a true bubble. This paper demonstrates that attempts to rationalize the bubble<br />

in this manner cannot be justified with the available data: the tulip mania really did<br />

produce a bubble. Moreover, the paper presents a model based on social networks and<br />

information cascades that explains the emergence of the bubble as well as its subsequent<br />

collapse. <strong>The</strong> salient feature of the tulip mania was not the astronomical prices that were<br />

paid for bulbs, but instead the remarkably dense and localized social network within<br />

which the tulip market was embedded.<br />

Keywords<br />

<strong>Tulip</strong> mania, financial bubbles, speculation, investment, social networks, Holland


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong>: <strong>The</strong> Social Politics of a Financial Bubble<br />

I shall eliminate…<br />

Those who ran with rabid lust after filthy profit,<br />

And poured so much of their poisoned juice<br />

That they nearly corrupted the real [flower-loving] people<br />

To no longer revere my flowers as they used to<br />

But weigh trash with pounds and bulbs by weight<br />

— Flora [the goddess of flowers], 1637. 1<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> tulip mania of the 1630s has long served as the epitome of the financial<br />

bubble. In his book Irrational Exuberance, Shiller calls it “the most famous bubble of<br />

all.” 2 No asset bubble is too small or too large or its bursting will be compared to the<br />

<strong>Dutch</strong> tulip craze. Indeed, references to tulips have come thick and fast in discussions of<br />

the current financial crisis. <strong>The</strong> Economist refers to “all those overpriced <strong>Dutch</strong> tulips” in<br />

an article examining financial instability, 3 while the New York Times asks: “It can’t<br />

possibly be that in the sophisticated, computerized 21 st century, we find ourselves<br />

experiencing the same kind of financial panic — the same kind of financial insanity,<br />

really — that has dogged mankind at least since the <strong>Dutch</strong> tulip mania of the 1630s. Can<br />

it?” 4<br />

<strong>The</strong> tulip craze has maintained its grip on the public imagination not just as a<br />

reference point in finance, but also as a fascinating episode in itself — witness Dumas’<br />

1 (De Verstoorde, 1637) (<strong>The</strong> angry and not-yet-dead Flora.) All translations are by the author.<br />

2 (Shiller, 2000, p. 177) Similarly, though Kindleberger’s standard work <strong>Mania</strong>s, Panics and Crashes<br />

offers only a very superficial discussion of the mania, he nonetheless lists it as the first of the “big 10<br />

financial bubbles” (Kindleberger & Aliber, 2005, p. 8)<br />

3 ("Wild-Animal Spirits," 2009)<br />

4 (Nocera, 2008)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 2<br />

classic novel <strong>The</strong> Black <strong>Tulip</strong> and Moggach’s more recent <strong>Tulip</strong> Fever. 5 In recent years,<br />

however, some authors have called into questions its status as an early example of a<br />

financial bubble. <strong>The</strong>re is some disagreement among economists on the proper definition<br />

of a bubble, but Shiller’s definition — “a situation in which temporarily high prices are<br />

sustained largely by investors’ enthusiasm rather than by consistent estimation of real<br />

value” — appears relatively uncontroversial. 6 <strong>The</strong> controversy lies in its<br />

operationalization: how does one judge whether “consistent estimation of real value” is<br />

taking place? Clearly, high prices do not suffice: the fact that single bulbs sold for more<br />

than the price of a house during the tulip mania appears foolish today, but it may well<br />

reflect the value placed on those bulbs by contemporaries.<br />

Several authors have challenged the tulip mania’s iconic status as a financial bubble.<br />

First, Garber has suggested that the pattern of price changes observed during the tulip<br />

craze matches the pattern one would expect for novel luxury goods in limited but<br />

gradually growing supply. 7 His argument is widely cited but rarely examined closely.<br />

More recently, Thompson has claimed that the dramatic increases in tulip prices during<br />

the winter of 1636-1637 were due to a shift in market instruments from standard futures<br />

contracts to options. 8 If either author is correct, the literature on financial bubbles may be<br />

forced to make do without this popular episode. As I show in this paper, however, both<br />

are wrong.<br />

5 (Moggach, 1999)<br />

6 (Shiller, 2000, p. xii)<br />

7 (Garber, 1989, 2000)<br />

8 (Thompson, 2006)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 3<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> tulip mania undeniably meets Shiller’s definition of a bubble, and as such<br />

deserves to retain its place as an early illustration of “the madness of crowds.” 9 More<br />

importantly, the episode sheds a valuable light on a feature of speculative bubbles often<br />

ignored by market fundamentalists: the impact of social networks and norms. <strong>The</strong> tulip<br />

mania illustrates the ease with which a bubble can emerge within comparatively small<br />

and densely connected social networks. <strong>The</strong> remain<strong>der</strong> of the paper is divided into three<br />

parts. <strong>The</strong> first part briefly presents the key features of the tulip craze. Next I analyze the<br />

available evidence on tulip prices during the mania, which demonstrates that a bubble did<br />

arise, and that claims to the contrary cannot be sustained by the data. <strong>The</strong> third part,<br />

finally, shifts the emphasis to the social context that made the bubble possible, but also<br />

limited its scope and duration.<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> Craze<br />

<strong>Tulip</strong>s arrived in Western Europe from Turkey during the sixteenth century. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

rapidly came to be prized above all other flowers, and the well-to-do were willing to pay<br />

quite extraordinary sums to obtain the latest, most spectacularly colored variety. 10<br />

Particularly prized were tulips with darker colored stripes and “flames” on a lighter<br />

background. Many of the most valuable striations were created, we now know, by a virus.<br />

This was not un<strong>der</strong>stood at the time, however, hampering the systematic development of<br />

new varieties. Moreover, such “flaming” tulips were always a risky investment, since it<br />

9 (Mackay, 1932 [1852])<br />

10 Indeed, a 1614 book of emblems displays a tulip alongside the proverb “A fool and his money are soon<br />

parted” (Visscher, 1614)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 4<br />

was never certain whether their patterns would be as desirable, and valuable, from one<br />

year to the next. 11 To minimize uncertainty, serious tulip collectors contracted to buy and<br />

sell bulbs while they were in bloom, making payment and taking delivery only later, once<br />

the bulbs were lifted from the ground.<br />

<strong>Tulip</strong> prices were high because supplies of the most exciting new varieties were<br />

extremely limited. <strong>The</strong> supply of the most famous tulip of the 1620s, the Semper<br />

Augustus was in the hands of a single owner, who held on to the bulbs as prices offered<br />

rose from 1000 gulden per bulb in 1623 to 3000 gulden per bulb in 1625. 12 When a<br />

Semper Augustus bulb was finally sold some time later, the owner attached the<br />

stipulation that the buyer could sell neither the bulb itself, nor any of its offsets — small<br />

bulbs that develop on the outside of the main bulb — without permission of the original<br />

seller. 13 <strong>The</strong> problematic combination of uncertainty about the quality of a bulb’s next<br />

flower and mostly informal inevitably resulted in some failed transactions. Indeed, most<br />

of our reliable knowledge about tulip prices during this period <strong>der</strong>ives from such<br />

transactions, since the disappointed party would often approach a notary to file an official<br />

complaint. Records of these complaints are still kept in the city archives of many cities in<br />

Holland, whereas almost no original transaction records remain. <strong>The</strong> first of these<br />

complaints show up in the city archives as early as 1611. 14<br />

11 (Roman, 1637b, p. 22)<br />

12 (Krelage, 1942a, pp. 31-33; <strong>van</strong> Wassenaer, 1625) <strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> currency at the time was the gulden,<br />

often translated as guil<strong>der</strong>. <strong>The</strong> annual earnings of a skilled artisan such as a carpenter around 1630<br />

were about 300 gulden (Goldgar, 2007, p. 225) At 3000 gulden, the Semper Augustus was valued at<br />

about 10 times the annual income of someone in the lower middle class.<br />

13 (Roman, 1637a, pp. 18-19)<br />

14 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 11-13)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 5<br />

<strong>The</strong> number of different varieties of tulips increased very rapidly during the 1620s<br />

and 1630s — far too rapidly for any consistent naming scheme to evolve. 15 Some names<br />

were descriptive, but many signaled high quality and the bulb’s original owner or town.<br />

Thus we find many tulips whose name begins with Admirael or Generael, applying<br />

military ranks to signify the fine quality of the bulb. Admirael <strong>van</strong> Enckhuysen was a<br />

bulb originally grown in the town of Enkhuizen, while the tulip grower Van <strong>der</strong> Eijck<br />

was the original owner of the first Generael <strong>van</strong> <strong>der</strong> Eijck bulb. 16 Despite the large<br />

number of varieties, supply remained quite limited, as new bulbs needed to grow for a<br />

number of years before they bloomed for the first time. Though there were dozens of<br />

highly prized varieties, the total supply for any given variety was frequently only a<br />

handful of bulbs, property of an even smaller number of growers.<br />

Until the early 1630s, the market for tulips was composed almost entirely of<br />

aficionados trading amongst themselves. <strong>The</strong>se were mostly wealthy merchants whose<br />

financial fortunes would not be negatively affected by the occasional disappointing<br />

purchase of a bulb that turned out to be less fine than expected. Moreover, as bulb lovers<br />

they also had a thorough knowledge of tulip growing and of the characteristics of<br />

different varieties. Most importantly, since transactions took place during the time when<br />

bulbs were in bloom, the quality of the flowers could be assessed. By 1634, however,<br />

15 By the peak of the mania in early 1637 about 500 different varieties had been developed in Holland.<br />

Few of these same varieties still exist today, but we have contemporary pictures of about 80% of them<br />

(Krelage, 1942a, p. 59)<br />

16 (Krelage, 1942a, pp. 35-38; see also Roman, 1637a, p. 16) Inevitably, name inflation occurred: one of<br />

the most famous varieties during the tulip craze was the Gouda bulb, named for the <strong>Dutch</strong> town.<br />

However, its original name was actually Generael <strong>der</strong> Generaelen <strong>van</strong> Gouda, i.e. “general of<br />

generals.”


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 6<br />

sales had begun to take place throughout the year. 17 A futures market developed shortly<br />

thereafter: people began to sell bulbs for which they had signed a contract but which they<br />

did not yet have in their possession. 18 This permitted tra<strong>der</strong>s to make a profit without ever<br />

having to plant a bulb of their own. Not surprisingly, it took little time for speculators to<br />

enter the market.<br />

A number of factors served as catalysts for speculation. First, <strong>Dutch</strong> commerce in<br />

general was flourishing during this period, creating new wealth not only at the elite levels<br />

but also among an increasingly prominent middle class. 19 Second, the large profits<br />

generated by the East Indian trade — as well as speculation in the shares of the <strong>Dutch</strong><br />

East India Company (VOC) — generated not only high incomes, but also a level of<br />

comfort with risky futures contracts. 20 Third, no guild controlled the tulip trade, so<br />

barriers to entry were comparatively low. 21 Finally, it has been suggested that the free<br />

coinage policy of the Bank of Amsterdam may have attracted additional money to<br />

Holland. 22<br />

One additional contributing factor deserves separate mention: the plague which<br />

ravaged Holland in 1635-1636. Amsterdam lost about 20% of its inhabitants over two<br />

17 (Velius, 1648)<br />

18 (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 206-207)<br />

19 Indeed, a near-contemporary account characterizes the tulip craze as a “remarkable example”<br />

(verwon<strong>der</strong>enswaardig exempel) of the growth in wealth and mass participation associated with<br />

commerce (Aitzema, 1669-1672, p. 2:503)<br />

20 Indeed, the <strong>Dutch</strong> appear to have had an appetite for risk in general. Goldgar cites numerous examples<br />

of contracts for the purchase or sale of bulbs that include side bets on the outcome of military<br />

campaigns, or the survival of parties to the contract (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 219-221)<br />

21 (Schama, 1988, p. 350)<br />

22 (French, 2006)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 7<br />

years. Haarlem, one of the centers of the bulb trade, lost more than 20% in 1635 alone. 23<br />

In fact, several contemporary authors drew a causal link from the tulip craze to the<br />

plague. <strong>The</strong> title of one pamphlet says it all: New Year’s Plague Mirror in which is on<br />

display God’s Just Plague-Punishment, for the attention of the well-to-do Netherlan<strong>der</strong>s<br />

in this bold, rotten Century. <strong>The</strong> implication was that God was punishing the bulb<br />

speculators for their limitless greed. 24 Recent writers reverse the causal arrow: the ever-<br />

present threat of a rapid death may well have inclined people towards taking greater<br />

risks. 25<br />

As prices began to rise and new, less knowledgeable tra<strong>der</strong>s entered the market, three<br />

new types of deals were introduced. First, transactions began to make explicit reference<br />

to a bulb’s weight. <strong>The</strong> first recorded disputes to mention bulb weights concerned<br />

contracts signed in the late summer of 1635. 26 Bulb weights were expressed in “azen”,<br />

with one “aas” equivalent to about 0.05 grams. Next, a lively trade developed in the<br />

offsets of bulbs. For example, buyers would offer a certain price per aas for the largest<br />

offset of a particular bulb. <strong>The</strong> total payment would be determined when the bulb was<br />

dug up and its offsets examined and weighed. 27 Finally, bulbs began to be sold in bulk,<br />

by weight. <strong>The</strong> archives record many deals for 1000 azen of a particular variety —<br />

23 (Noordegraaf & Valk, 1996, p. 54)<br />

24 <strong>The</strong> title in <strong>Dutch</strong> is: Nieu-Iaers Pest-Spiegel waer in te sien is de Rechtveerdighe Pest-straffe Gods<br />

voorghestelt tot opmerck <strong>der</strong> weeldige Ne<strong>der</strong>-Lan<strong>der</strong>s in dese snoode bedurven Eeuwe. <strong>The</strong> pamphlet,<br />

originally published in Haarlem, was sufficiently popular to be reprinted almost immediately in<br />

neighbouring towns (<strong>The</strong>uniszoon <strong>van</strong> <strong>der</strong> Lust, 1637).<br />

25 (E.g. Garber, 2000, pp. 37-38; Goldgar, 2007, pp. 254-260)<br />

26 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 17)<br />

27 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 23, 29, 32)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 8<br />

usually about 3-6 bulbs. Lesser-valued cultivars could also be traded by the pound,<br />

roughly 30-60 bulbs.<br />

This last innovation in particular fueled the speculative bubble. As the epigram<br />

opening the paper indicates, contemporary observers recognized this too, and many<br />

looked askance (partially out of envy) at those who traded primarily in so-called ‘pound<br />

goods.’ Earlier contracts had always been linked to specific bulbs. However, a contract<br />

for 1000 azen Gouda, for example, could be filled with any set of Gouda bulbs the seller<br />

chose. With the link to specific bulbs severed, it became possible to engage in<br />

transactions in which neither party had any idea about the eventual source of the bulbs.<br />

Moreover, no real knowledge of either tulips or their bulbs was required, only a sense of<br />

the going rate per aas for a particular tulip variety. Where prices had risen gradually but<br />

steadily over the preceding years, the rise accelerated once these bulk contracts were<br />

introduced into the market. Single-bulb prices appreciated faster too, but prices rose<br />

fastest on the bulk contracts.<br />

<strong>The</strong> elimination of the need to have one’s own bulb garden or even to be a<br />

connoisseur of tulips, combined with the lure of quick and easy profits, drew new<br />

entrants into the tulip market in growing numbers beginning in the fall of 1635. As new<br />

entrants multiplied, transactions increasingly moved from the gardens and drawing rooms<br />

of the most active collectors to regular, organized venues, usually at local inns. A system<br />

of ‘colleges’ soon developed across the main towns of Holland. <strong>The</strong>se colleges,<br />

composed of a core of regular tra<strong>der</strong>s, met at a specific inn two or three times per week,<br />

usually in the evening (most tra<strong>der</strong>s held on to their day jobs). Outsi<strong>der</strong>s were welcome,<br />

but needed to be introduced first. Most deals took places with the mediation of one or two


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 9<br />

“neutral” observers, and all sales were sealed with the payment of a small surcharge<br />

called the “wijnkoop” (wine purchase/fee) of about 2.5%. <strong>The</strong>se funds were spent<br />

immediately by the members of the college in attendance, on food, drink and tobacco,<br />

thus lubricating the deal-making. Wijnkoop monies also paid for lamps and a fire, as well<br />

as tips for the serving girls. Even the poor were not forgotten, and some alms were set<br />

aside. 28 Prominent tulip collectors and growers regularly attended these colleges, and<br />

some of the more successful tra<strong>der</strong>s in the colleges developed ties to a number of<br />

collectors, further tightening the social networks within which all were embedded. 29<br />

<strong>The</strong> real speculative bubble did not last very long. Prices began to rise faster once the<br />

bulbs had been planted in October 1636. Bulk contracts became increasingly common by<br />

December 1636, giving the market a final boost. Peak prices were paid during the last<br />

few days of January and first few days of February 1637. From the beginning of this<br />

three-month period to the end, some individual bulbs were sold as many as 5-10 times,<br />

and increased more than ten-fold in price, while bulk quantities of cheaper goods<br />

increased as much as twenty-fold. A contemporary account notes that even varieties for<br />

which there had been no demand previously because they were too common or plain now<br />

were sold for large sums. 30 Although disquiet about skyrocketing prices had been<br />

building, the end still arrived suddenly and unexpectedly, with plummeting prices for<br />

some of the most common pound goods in Haarlem on February 3rd. A public auction of<br />

28 (Roman, 1637b, p. 5)<br />

29 (Goldgar, 2007)<br />

30 (Roman, 1637b, p. 24)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 10<br />

choice bulbs in Alkmaar on February 5th garnered peak prices, 31 but this was merely a<br />

last hurrah. 32 By February 7th, it had become clear throughout the main trading centers<br />

that the market had crashed. I discuss the crisis and its resolution in more detail below.<br />

First however, we need to establish that a bubble indeed took place, by taking a closer<br />

look at the available data on bulb prices.<br />

Data on <strong>Tulip</strong> Prices<br />

Most tulip contracts were informal, and many were probably not even written down.<br />

Those that were committed to paper were generally torn up once completed. Moreover,<br />

there were no regular newspapers to cover the crisis as it unfolded: weekly newspapers<br />

only emerged in most Holland towns in the 1660s. However, the tulip bubble fascinated<br />

contemporary observers, who produced a wealth of — mostly critical — pamphlets,<br />

which accordingly constitute one of the main sources of empirical data on tulip prices. 33<br />

Unfortunately, contemporary historiographers relied almost exclusively on these<br />

pamphlets, even where access to the principals and other original documents would have<br />

been feasible. 34 Pamphlet authors were usually more interested in criticizing — or , in a<br />

few case, defending — the bulb trade than in explaining it. As a result, most of the useful<br />

31 (Lijste <strong>van</strong> Eenighe Tulpaen, 1637)<br />

32 Though distances between Holland towns were not great, people did not travel frequently. As noted,<br />

most bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s had other professions and traveling did take time away from their other pursuits. As a<br />

result, the peak did not occur on the same day all across Holland (Krelage, 1942a, pp. 50-51)<br />

33 (Krelage, 1942b; Posthumus, 1926)<br />

34 (E.g. Aitzema, 1669-1672, p. 2313)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 11<br />

specific information about the tulip mania we have today is drawn from a series of just<br />

three pamphlets.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se pamphlets were published — and likely written —by Adriaen Roman in<br />

Haarlem, between February and May 1637. 35 Each is presented in the form of a dialogue<br />

between two main characters, Gaergoedt (GreedyGoods) and Waermondt (Truemouth).<br />

Gaergoedt is a well-to-do weaver who has been active as a bulb tra<strong>der</strong>, and who<br />

un<strong>der</strong>takes to educate Waermondt about the tulip market, in or<strong>der</strong> to explain and defend<br />

his actions. Waermondt, in response, offers moralistic tales intended to highlight the folly<br />

of various aspects of the tulip mania. One of the most valuable features of these dialogues<br />

is that they reproduce sample bulb sale contracts as well as data on the prices fetched for<br />

particular bulbs near the beginning and towards the end of the bubble. <strong>The</strong>re is little firm<br />

corroboration for the data provided in these dialogues, and they can be shown to contain<br />

some errors. Accordingly, no single price or weight can be consi<strong>der</strong>ed entirely reliable.<br />

Nevertheless, there is no reason to suspect any systematic distortion of the price<br />

information, and most students of the tulip mania have accepted it as valid. 36<br />

Similar problems hamper the use of the sole other source of price data: complaints<br />

and legal cases whose records survive in town archives. Few students of the tulip craze<br />

have consulted these archives themselves: the only recent exceptions I am aware of are<br />

35 (Roman, 1637a, 1637b, 1637c)<br />

36 <strong>The</strong> dialogues are fictional, and their publisher/author does not pretend otherwise, which might lead us<br />

to suspect all of the reported prices. Moreover, they have an agenda, which is to highlight the folly of<br />

the tulip mania. However, no contemporary pamphlet authors challenged the data provided in these<br />

dialogues, and some of the prices listed in the dialogues match those printed in a broadside reporting<br />

the results of the Alkmaar auction of 5 Feb. 1637, at which some of the highest prices for any bulbs<br />

were recorded (Lijste <strong>van</strong> Eenighe Tulpaen, 1637). Still, some of the prices in the dialogues are faulty<br />

transcriptions from the Alkmaar auction. For example, example, a bulb of 171 azen that sold for 173<br />

gulden is listed in the dialogue as weighing just 71 azen but selling for 175 gulden.


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 12<br />

Dash and Goldgar. 37 Instead, most rely on the collection of transcriptions published<br />

during the 1920s and 1930s by Posthumus. 38 Unfortunately, Goldgar has found<br />

Posthumus’ transcriptions to be “extremely sloppy” and riddled with errors. 39 In other<br />

words, no single piece of evidence is completely reliable here either. All in all, the<br />

available price evidence is both thin and somewhat uncertain. We have about 400 price<br />

points, the vast majority of which refer to peak prices only. About 65 data points provide<br />

pre-peak prices, from before late January 1637. Of these, about 50 concern the three<br />

month-period of the bubble from November through January. <strong>The</strong>se 50 observations<br />

reference 30 different varieties of tulips. On the far side of the peak, we have data on only<br />

about 5 transactions for the remain<strong>der</strong> of 1637 and the first part of 1638. We do,<br />

however, have a few general statements in the third dialogue about the drastic drop in<br />

value after the crash.<br />

Writers on the tulip mania have adopted different strategies to overcome the difficulty<br />

of drawing solid conclusions based on such limited data. <strong>The</strong> simplest tactic is to rely<br />

heavily on the hyperbole found in the pamphlets. For example, the post-script to the first<br />

dialogue between Gaergoedt and Waermondt claims that “some goods ran so high that<br />

one or two guldens became one hundred, sometimes more.” 40 If true, this would be strong<br />

evidence for a bubble. However, the prices listed in the dialogues — which are explicitly<br />

intended to illustrate the dramatic nature of the price increases observed — do not<br />

37 (Dash, 1999; Goldgar, 2007)<br />

38 (Posthumus, 1927, 1934)<br />

39 (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 328-329, fn. 329)<br />

40 (Roman, 1637b, p. 23)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 13<br />

support this claim, and only the most superficial treatments of the tulip mania take it<br />

seriously.<br />

A more promising approach is to interpolate based on the available data, as Garber<br />

does. 41 Garber generates 16 charts showing the price evolution of different tulip varieties<br />

by connecting observations in a straight line. However, each chart has only a few data<br />

points: three of them have only an initial and a final price. While the charts demonstrate<br />

that prices rose a lot, they cannot be used to draw any conclusions about the price<br />

trajectory between the individual observations. Simply imposing a straight line<br />

contradicts all contemporary accounts, which indicate a gradual increase at first, with a<br />

far steeper slope near the end of the bubble.<br />

Garber’s data on the other side of the peak suffer the same flaw. As noted earlier, we<br />

have very little data from the period immediately following the bubble. Garber, therefore,<br />

is forced to rely on prices from a sale in 1642/43. All one can do with such data is<br />

calculate average annual depreciation; they say nothing about the actual shape of the<br />

price curve. Nevertheless, Garber concludes that “the crash of February 1637 for rare<br />

bulbs was not of extraordinary magnitude” simply by assuming a linear price decline for<br />

the period between the end of the crash and 1642. 42 However, if we trust the peak price<br />

data offered in the dialogues — as Garber does — we must also take seriously the<br />

evidence they provide on the values of bulbs after the crash. Gaergoedt notes that it is<br />

hard to estimate price levels “since there is no demand for bulbs; everybody is silent.”<br />

Nevertheless, he records that a garden filled with common varieties of tulips brought only<br />

41 (Garber, 1989, 2000)<br />

42 (Garber, 2000, p. 70)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 14<br />

about one hundredth of the price it might have fetched at the peak. More importantly for<br />

our purposes, a sale of several individual bulbs only fetched about 22 gulden each,<br />

whereas Gaergoedt suggests they might have been worth 400 gulden at their peak. 43 This<br />

implies that prices of individual bulbs fell by as much as 95% within a few months,<br />

invalidating Garber’s assumption of a steady, linear drop in prices over the course of the<br />

six subsequent years. Garber does acknowledge the price surge and decline in the more<br />

common bulbs, sold in bulk, but waves away the problem by blaming it on the lack of<br />

regulation of contracts within the colleges. 44 I address this argument in more detail<br />

below.<br />

Interpolating from one observation to the next would be less problematic if we had<br />

more data points, with less time elapsing from one to the next. This might be possible if<br />

we could generate an index of relative prices that permits comparisons across different<br />

tulip varieties. Thompson’s argument about the price developments in the tulip market<br />

relies on the validity of such an index. 45 However, Thompson fails to address some fatal<br />

problems with this approach. First, an index must be based on price observations taken at<br />

the same point in time, but Thompson <strong>der</strong>ives his baseline from a book of tulip paintings<br />

for which neither the source nor the date of the prices listed are known. 46 Second, not all<br />

bulb sales are directly comparable. Transactions may involve offsets, bulbs, or bulbs in<br />

43 (Roman, 1637a, p. 12). Among these latter bulbs was a Gheel ende Root <strong>van</strong> Leyden. At the height of<br />

the bubble, a large bulb of this variety was sold for 550 gulden, so an estimated value of 400 gulden for<br />

a single bulb is not unreasonable (Lijste <strong>van</strong> Eenighe Tulpaen, 1637)<br />

44 (Garber, 2000, p. 81)<br />

45 (Thompson, 2006)<br />

46 A number of the prices <strong>der</strong>ive from the February 5th auction, but most do not. <strong>The</strong> book has been<br />

digitized and can be seen at http://library.wur.nl/tulips/blauw_content.html (accessed 15 February<br />

2009).


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 15<br />

bulk; the value per aas is not the same across these three transaction types, with bulk<br />

goods worth the least and offsets the most. Nor does the value of a bulb increase linearly<br />

with its weight. 47 <strong>The</strong> third problem, fatal all by itself, is that an index can only be used to<br />

compare prices for different varieties at different points in time if we assume, against all<br />

the available evidence, that the shape of the price curve over time is identical for every<br />

tulip variety, so that relative prices remain constant. 48<br />

In sum, neither Garber’s nor Thompson’s attempts to explain away the tulip bubble<br />

can be sustained by the available data. Arguing that price fluctuations did not exceed<br />

those supported by market fundamentals, as Garber does, requires ignoring key points of<br />

evidence from the post-crash period, as well as assuming that prices increased and<br />

decreased linearly prior to and after the peak, an assumption contradicted by every<br />

contemporary account. Making more precise claims about the timing of particular aspects<br />

of the bubble, as Thompson does, requires ignoring the problems inherent in aggregating<br />

price information for bulbs of different weights and varieties at different points in time,<br />

as well as placing complete faith in the accuracy of each individual price observation.<br />

Though the data are limited, they quite clearly indicate a rapid rise in prices, accelerating<br />

through December 1636 and January 1637, followed by a steep and sudden decline after<br />

the first week of February. Contemporary pamphlets unanimously support this picture.<br />

47 <strong>The</strong> results of the February 5th auction suggest that a doubling in weight is associated with a ≈50%<br />

increase in price. Garber ignores this problem too (Garber, 2000, p. ch. 8)<br />

48 To give just one example, the Gouda had doubled in price before the Oudenaerde began increasing<br />

rapidly in price, while the Switser did not really start gaining in value until three weeks later still. If we<br />

have only one pre-peak price for a bulb, there is no way to know where on its price curve to locate it —<br />

has it already gained most of its value, or is the steepest rise still to come? Relative prices across<br />

different bulbs changed day by day.


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 16<br />

Social and Informational Features of the Bubble<br />

How, then, can we explain this bubble? In this section, I argue that the key to the<br />

explanation lies in the dense social networks and strong social norms within which<br />

commerce in Holland was embedded at the time. Efficient market models — of the kind<br />

proposed by both Garber and Thompson — assume that those who bought and sold rare<br />

and bulk bulbs used their own private knowledge about the fundamental supply of and<br />

demand for various bulbs. Prices might rise while increases in fundamental (non-<br />

speculative) demand exceeded increases in supply, but they would be kept un<strong>der</strong> control.<br />

Bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s would begin selling once prices threatened to deviate from un<strong>der</strong>lying<br />

fundamentals. As we have seen, however, in the winter of 1636/37 people behaved<br />

differently. Still, the bubble did not develop because the tra<strong>der</strong>s’ private knowledge about<br />

the actual supply of particular bulbs was faulty. As we shall see, the market was quite<br />

localized, and those active in the trade were familiar with the gardens where the tulips<br />

were planted and with the tulips themselves.<br />

<strong>The</strong> key factor, instead, was the social connectedness among tulip tra<strong>der</strong>s, who were<br />

linked to one another by religion, by marriage, by trade, etc. As a result, market<br />

participants assigned a greater weight to the decisions of other tra<strong>der</strong>s than they would<br />

have if they had interacted only through the arms-length transactions of the market. 49<br />

Aggregated across the entire market, these decisions came to outweigh the influence of<br />

private knowledge, setting the bubble in motion. <strong>The</strong> tulip bubble thus emerged as the<br />

49 (Cf. Uzzi, 1999)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 17<br />

result of an information cascade. 50 <strong>The</strong> basic insight associated with such cascades is<br />

individuals may rationally ignore their own private information and be guided by the<br />

decisions of others. Applied to markets this means that people may rationally ignore their<br />

own knowledge about the demand for or supply of a particular good. Crucially, this also<br />

implies that lack of knowledge need not be an impediment to a rational actor’s entrance<br />

into a market.<br />

In an elegant application of an information transmission model to investment bubbles,<br />

Hong, Scheinkman, and Xiong show how a bubble can emerge in a situation where<br />

technological innovation has ren<strong>der</strong>ed the knowledge of some advisors much less<br />

valuable. 51 Those advisors who do un<strong>der</strong>stand the innovation have an incentive to signal<br />

their type by inflating their forecasts so as to stand out from those whose advice is now<br />

less valuable. If there are many naïve investors who accept any forecast at face value, a<br />

bubble readily emerges. <strong>The</strong> mechanism I propose here is similar in many respects. <strong>The</strong><br />

crucial difference is that investors and advisors are not separate groups. This changes<br />

some of the basic dynamics and makes the social connections among the actors rather<br />

more significant.<br />

In his earlier work on the science of social networks, Watts suggests that a densely<br />

connected network may be resistant to information cascades, since “the more people<br />

whose actions or opinions you take into account before making a decision, the less<br />

influence any one of them will have.” 52 <strong>The</strong> idea is that all individuals are “locally stable”<br />

50 (Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, & Welch, 1992)<br />

51 (Hong, Scheinkman, & Xiong, 2008; cf. Nairn, 2002)<br />

52 (Watts, 2003, p. 240)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 18<br />

and hence no shock, however large, to a single node in the network is likely to result in<br />

any kind of cascade. However, that conclusion only applies if all members of the network<br />

can be observed at once. If members of the network act in small groups, the potential<br />

stabilizing influence of the rest of the network largely disappears. In fact, in subsequent<br />

research, Watts has found that cascades are made possible by “the presence… of a critical<br />

mass of easily influenced people, each of whom adopts… after being exposed to a single<br />

adopting neighbor.” 53 As we shall see, the tulip bubble contains features of both of these<br />

scenarios. <strong>The</strong> overall connectedness of the social network actually made things less,<br />

rather than more, stable; and a small-group setting made it unnecessary for people to be<br />

so naïve that exposure to just a single neighbor drove their decisions.<br />

<strong>The</strong> social logic behind the tulip bubble can be illustrated by way of analogy to the art<br />

auction market. Art dealer X, who has bought and sold art at major auctions for years,<br />

will know most of the other active art dealers — especially the local ones — and will<br />

have come to trust their knowledge and judgment. Imagine that a piece of art outside X’s<br />

area of expertise has caught her eye. She would like to acquire it, but does not wish to<br />

pay more than the work is worth. Three possible strategies readily suggest themselves: 1)<br />

research the value of the piece, thus acquiring sufficient private knowledge to judge<br />

value; 2) see how much her colleagues have recently bid on comparable pieces; and 3)<br />

simply outbid any of her colleagues whose judgment she trusts, but stop bidding if an<br />

unknown person drives up the bid further. No strategy can eliminate all uncertainty: no<br />

two pieces of art are exactly alike, and even art experts are not always sure how much a<br />

work of art might fetch on the open market. Hence, strategy 1 may not be worth pursuing,<br />

53 (Watts, 2007)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 19<br />

since it is not guaranteed to repay the consi<strong>der</strong>able costs involved in acquiring sufficient<br />

knowledge, especially compared to the far more modest costs associated with strategies 2<br />

or 3. This implies that the adoption of strategies 2 or 3 may be rational, even if X<br />

recognizes that these strategies are far riskier.<br />

<strong>The</strong> risk associated with strategy 3 is the most obvious. If art buyers X and Y each<br />

trust the knowledge and judgment of the other, they may end up in a bidding contest well<br />

beyond the “fundamental” value of the piece, up to a point where the price reaches a level<br />

that even the imperfect knowledge of either X or Y tells her that it is not worth that much.<br />

At this point, she will stop bidding, leaving the other to pay far too much. <strong>The</strong> risks with<br />

strategy 2 are less obvious but no less severe. <strong>The</strong> strategy will work well if bids made in<br />

the recent past on similar pieces by other dealers were based on private knowledge, i.e.<br />

on strategy 1. However, if they were based on strategies 2 or 3, the actions of X will<br />

simply reinforce the misvaluation, and help generate an information cascade. It is easy to<br />

see how the social context — art dealers who know and trust one another — makes such<br />

outcomes far more likely than if nobody trusted the knowledge and judgment of her<br />

colleagues. After all, the less one’s confidence in one’s fellow dealers, the greater is the<br />

incentive to acquire adequate private knowledge.<br />

Now imagine novice art dealers X1 through Xn who, one after the other, decide to get<br />

involved in the market, attracted by the lure of easy money, or because their disposable<br />

incomes has risen consi<strong>der</strong>ably in recent times. <strong>The</strong>y can begin purchasing art most easily<br />

by adopting strategies 2 and 3 exclusively. However, doing so reduces the fraction of the<br />

auction participants with private knowledge. As a result, for each successive<br />

collector/dealer that enters the market in this manner, there is a smaller likelihood that a


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 20<br />

randomly chosen auction participant has valuable private knowledge. Nevertheless, it<br />

may continue to be rational for each new entrant not to invest resources in acquiring<br />

private knowledge. Finally, the rising prices that result from such an information cascade<br />

will attract additional works of art to the auction house. This further reduces the<br />

comparative value of the private information of dealers who have been active longer,<br />

because their knowledge of the total supply will be less complete.<br />

Translating this basic model to the <strong>Dutch</strong> tulip mania is relatively straightforward. In<br />

what follows, I first characterize the market by discussing the supply of bulbs, the nature<br />

of tulip sale contracts and the community of tulip tra<strong>der</strong>s. Next I apply the basic logic<br />

presented in the preceding paragraphs to the case of the tulip bubble. I show that the<br />

bubble logically emerged from a combination of two factors: an innovation in the market<br />

— bulbs sold in bulb, by total weight — and the entry of new tra<strong>der</strong>s embedded<br />

alongside existing bulb lovers in a densely connected social network. A brief discussion<br />

of the aftermath of the bubble un<strong>der</strong>scores the key role played by these two factors. As<br />

noted earlier, a number of facilitating factors were undeniably present: the <strong>Dutch</strong> were<br />

comfortable with speculation, the plague may have made them more risk-acceptant, tulip<br />

trading was rarely the sole source of income for the participants, and no guild existed to<br />

impose strict regulations and penalties. But without the tight social network<br />

encompassing all tra<strong>der</strong>s and the introduction of a new type of bulb contracts, we would<br />

not have seen a bubble.<br />

<strong>The</strong> supply of bulbs was comparatively fixed; it increased through the growth of<br />

offsets, but these took several years to become full-grown bulbs capable of flowering and<br />

creating their own offsets. With the newest varieties often in greatest demand, growers in


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 21<br />

possession of such bulbs could be fairly certain of controlling the market for a few years.<br />

<strong>The</strong> rapid expansion of the professional and merchant class within the towns of Holland<br />

meant that demand easily kept pace with the development of new varieties. With demand<br />

growing faster than supply, as it did starting in the early 1630s, it is no surprise that<br />

prices rose, or that a market emerged for lower-quality bulbs too. Not surprisingly, rising<br />

prices attracted others to the market, and made existing bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s more enthusiastic.<br />

Eventually, however, supply was bound to outstrip demand: the bulb supply could<br />

grow faster than did that of wealthy burghers, and there was a limit to the number of<br />

recognizably different varieties that could be developed. Prices would, therefore<br />

inevitably fall in the medium term. This, in essence, is the story told by Garber, and it<br />

adequately explains both the rise in prices up to the summer of 1636 and the gradual<br />

decline that appears to have set in once the crash had been sorted out by the late summer<br />

of 1637. As we have seen, however, it cannot account for the dramatic increase in the<br />

prices not just of the bulk goods, but also of the rarest bulbs, in the fall and winter of<br />

1636-1637. Nor does it explain the crash that followed.<br />

Most tulip sales followed a standard format. Transactions in the colleges were<br />

conducted in a ritualized fashion, with separate procedures for sales and purchases, and<br />

were confirmed with the payment of the “wijnkoop” fee. 54 As Schama notes, “what is<br />

actually striking about the popular-speculative phase of the tulip mania is how quickly it<br />

54 <strong>The</strong> procedures are described in (Roman, 1637c, p. 23) and (Roman, 1637b, pp. 4-5), respectively.<br />

Sales were open to multiple bid<strong>der</strong>s and were done in an auction format, whereas purchases were<br />

conducted as bilateral negotiations in which buyers and sellers tried to find a mutually acceptable<br />

middle ground. Detailed explanations can be found in (Krelage, 1942a, pp. 70-73). In addition to<br />

entering the sale in the college’s ledger, both sides to a transaction often wrote out a small sales note,<br />

or enter the text in their own ledgers. <strong>The</strong> second dialogue between Gaergoedt and Waermondt gives<br />

some examples of the latter (Roman, 1637c, p. 14).


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 22<br />

improvised highly ritualized and formal conventions in which to conduct its trade.” 55 <strong>The</strong><br />

sales agreement provided for simultaneous payment and delivery only at the moment a<br />

bulb was dug up, with the opportunity to verify the flower beforehand. 56 Deals struck<br />

outside the blooming period therefore always involved some features of a futures<br />

transaction. Deals were usually recorded in a ledger, either that of a notary or that of one<br />

of the colleges.<br />

Even with the norms governing the manner of buying and selling, uncertainties<br />

remained: buyers worried about the quality of the bulbs they were buying, while sellers<br />

worried about being paid in full. As a result, contracts themselves were subject to norms<br />

too. A standard, but implicit, feature of sales contracts was that when a bulb turned out to<br />

be of a different variety than promised, the sale was nullified, and the seller did not have<br />

to accept it. 57 To reassure the seller, a system of “borgen” — guarantors of payment —<br />

emerged, in which one or two friends or relatives of the buyer would guarantee payment<br />

if the buyer could not or would not pay. In addition, buyers often explicitly pledged their<br />

assets. A sample contract listed in the second dialogue — and described as being<br />

representative of almost all such contracts — states: “in case of non-payment of the<br />

aforementioned sum, I hereby pledge all my goods, movable and immovable, placing<br />

them un<strong>der</strong> the control of all the laws and courts.” 58 Such language makes it hard to<br />

sustain either Garber’s claim that these deals were the outcome of “a meaningless winter<br />

drinking game” with insufficient “internal control over the nature of contracts” or<br />

55 (Schama, 1988, p. 359)<br />

56 (Cf. Goldgar, 2007, p. 241)<br />

57 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 85)<br />

58 (Roman, 1637c, p. 15)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 23<br />

Thompson’s odd assertion that tra<strong>der</strong>s all intuited in December 1636 that the nature of<br />

tulip contracts had suddenly but fundamentally changed. 59<br />

Though some trading in bulbs took place among towns and even across bor<strong>der</strong>s, there<br />

was virtually no systematic cultivation of bulbs for trade during the tulip mania; most<br />

growers were aficionados working in their own small gardens. 60 Notarized complaints<br />

make clear that the main participants regularly visited the various gardens around town in<br />

which tulips were planted, and hence were quite knowledgeable about the locally<br />

available supply of particular varieties, and even the quality of individual bulbs. 61 <strong>The</strong><br />

picture that emerges is one of mostly local markets within individual towns. Complaints<br />

still on file in the <strong>Dutch</strong> archives reinforce this impression: most recount disputes<br />

between tra<strong>der</strong>s from the same town, who all knew one another quite well.<br />

In addition, the total number of active participants in the tulip market appears to have<br />

been comparatively small, ranging from several dozen in the smaller towns such as<br />

Enkhuizen or Hoorn to several hundred in Haarlem. 62 More than one merchant appears<br />

just once in the archival record, purchasing or selling just a single bulb from or for his<br />

garden, so the number of regular tra<strong>der</strong>s was smaller still. In fact, the first dialogue notes<br />

59 (Garber, 2000, p. 81; Thompson, 2006)<br />

60 (Krelage, 1942a, p. 69). Bulb exports only began to take off in the second half of the seventeenth<br />

century, after the tulip mania had ended. Even then, Krelage notes, only a few growers aimed at the<br />

export market, and quantities were small — most foreign buyers were just interested in a single bulb of<br />

a particular variety (Krelage, 1942a, p. 102; see also Krelage, 1946, pp. 7-8,269-275)<br />

61 (E.g. Posthumus, 1927, p. 16). A contract dispute describes how a Haarlem baker who was interested<br />

in buying a bulb from a local merchant in one college visited another college within town and received<br />

additional information about that same bulb. This indicates just how small and well-informed the<br />

market was (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 27-28)<br />

62 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 137)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 24<br />

that new participants in the colleges attracted immediate notice. 63 Significantly, most of<br />

those active in the tulip trade in a given town were closely connected through several<br />

different networks. Many were related by blood or by marriage, a disproportionate<br />

number were Mennonites, and a consi<strong>der</strong>able number appear to have engaged in mutual<br />

business transactions unrelated to the tulip trade. 64 <strong>The</strong>se close ties further facilitated the<br />

rapid dissemination of information among tra<strong>der</strong>s, but they may also have given new<br />

tra<strong>der</strong>s an inflated sense of the expertise of their peers.<br />

<strong>The</strong> fact that most of the bulb trade was localized, and that it appears not to have<br />

spread much beyond a about a dozen <strong>Dutch</strong> towns, helps explain why the end of the tulip<br />

mania had only a minor impact on the rest of the <strong>Dutch</strong> economy. 65 In fact, though there<br />

is some disagreement among historians about rates of growth in the <strong>Dutch</strong> economy<br />

during this period, nobody seriously suggests that the tulip mania had a sizeable impact<br />

on its fortunes. 66 <strong>The</strong> collapse of the tulip bubble even failed to cause much local<br />

economic dislocation. Almost all tulip tra<strong>der</strong>s had other careers — they were merchants,<br />

successful artisans, or professionals — and most were comparatively wealthy. A few of<br />

the poorer tulip speculators may have faced economic ruin, but most of the active bulb<br />

63 (Roman, 1637b, p. 4)<br />

64 (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 146-149)<br />

65 Claims to the contrary in the literature are largely due to uncritical copying from Mackay’s<br />

sensationalist account, which declares that “the commerce of the country suffered a severe shock, from<br />

which it was many years ere it recovered (Mackay, 1932 [1852], p. 97).”<br />

66 (E.g. de Vries & <strong>van</strong> <strong>der</strong> Woude, 1997, pp. 150-151; Israel, 1995, p. 533)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 25<br />

tra<strong>der</strong>s remained quite prosperous in the late 1630s, despite losing all of their paper<br />

profits from the bubble. 67<br />

<strong>The</strong> tulip market functioned efficiently as long as two conditions were met: the<br />

tra<strong>der</strong>s all knew one another as fellow tulip aficionados, and they all had ample private<br />

information about the market, i.e. about the supply and quality of individual bulbs. As we<br />

have seen, the first of these conditions probably applied until 1635, and the second until<br />

1636. When novice tra<strong>der</strong>s entered the market, it became less stable, because this<br />

produced a drop in the average amount of expertise. Once a number of new tra<strong>der</strong>s had<br />

entered the market, it became increasingly difficult to distinguish those with solid private<br />

knowledge from those who were simply following the crowd. <strong>The</strong> final straw was the<br />

introduction of bulk sales. As noted earlier, these constituted a new kind of trade, no<br />

longer linked to individual bulbs. This meant that the private knowledge of established<br />

bulb lovers was suddenly much less rele<strong>van</strong>t.<br />

Returning to the art auction analogy, it was as though it had become possible to buy<br />

and sell a piece of art to be named later by the seller, and even for the seller to import that<br />

piece from elsewhere. Pamphlets and town records alike suggest that the established tulip<br />

tra<strong>der</strong>s were not initially active in this new trade, implying that prices were determined<br />

almost exclusively by tra<strong>der</strong>s playing strategies 2 and 3 from our art auction example,<br />

with the latter dominant initially. <strong>The</strong> bubble which followed inevitably spread to the rare<br />

bulb trade. After all, the two trades were linked: new tra<strong>der</strong>s were also interested in the<br />

67 (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 166-167, 247-169). Though many accounts of the bubble suggest that people from<br />

all walks of life were involved, these claims appear to <strong>der</strong>ive from some hyperbole in the first dialogue<br />

between Gaergoedt and Waermondt, where the latter claims that “daughters and maids, farmers and<br />

noblemen, even letter carriers… [and] chimney-sweeps” had entered the speculation (Roman, 1637b,<br />

p. 18)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 26<br />

rare bulbs, and rare bulb buyers were not immune to the lure of profits from the faster-<br />

rising prices of bulk sales. Moreover, a number of bulb lovers may have convinced<br />

themselves that they un<strong>der</strong>stood the market better than the latest entrants — that their<br />

private knowledge of individual bulbs had some value in this context too.<br />

In the end, it probably did. Prices could rise consi<strong>der</strong>ably as long as bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s —<br />

new entrants as well as established tulip lovers — continued to play strategies 2 and 3.<br />

Tra<strong>der</strong>s could rationalize rising prices by assuming that all new entrants in the market<br />

wanted bulbs to plant rather than merely for speculation — in other words, that<br />

“fundamental” demand had increased several times over. Moreover, (paper) profits made<br />

from trading bulk goods could be used to bid higher sums for prized individual bulbs. But<br />

there were limits to the price increases one could rationalize for either rare bulbs or bulk<br />

goods. For bulk goods, bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s who had been active for some years knew how long<br />

these varieties had been around, and how easily additional supplies could be found, not<br />

just in Holland, but also abroad. At some point, rising prices in Holland would inevitably<br />

begin to attract tulips from France or Germany.<br />

Most of the rare bulbs, in contrast, were new varieties, for which the supply was<br />

inelastic. Moreover, all established bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s knew who owned those bulbs. Here, the<br />

built-in limit was the price beyond which even the wealthiest merchants would not be<br />

interested in acquiring a bulb. That such a limit existed was clear from the beginning:<br />

even at the height of its desirability, for example, the famous Semper Augustus had never<br />

fetched prices that were beyond the reach of most bulb lovers — they simply did not wish<br />

to own it at all costs. Since private knowledge was more significant in rare bulb trades,<br />

this bubble did not expand as far. In turn, this implied that the bursting of the bubble


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 27<br />

would lead to less of a price collapse. <strong>The</strong> limited price data we have suggest that this is<br />

exactly what happened. Prices for pound goods could rise further because private<br />

knowledge mattered less: there was more uncertainty both about local supplies and about<br />

the price level that would attract imports.<br />

In the end, the bubble reached its limit first for the so-called pound goods. By the end<br />

of 1636 numerous outsi<strong>der</strong>s were already predicting an imminent crash. 68 As January<br />

progressed, and prices rose ever faster, tra<strong>der</strong>s, too, began to fear that prices might be<br />

unsustainable. 69 Moreover, the dense social networks joining all tulip tra<strong>der</strong>s guaranteed<br />

that such fears were common knowledge. Things went sour in Haarlem first, on February<br />

3rd. Waermondt, in the first dialogue, recounts the episode. 70 Members of a college<br />

decided to test market confidence by putting up for sale amongst themselves bulk<br />

quantities of common tulips — Switsers or Croonen. Just one buyer made any bids in<br />

three successive sales, and each of the sellers accepted his offer, even though the sum he<br />

offered was successively 15% below, 25% below, and finally 35% below recent prices<br />

for comparable bulbs. News of this precipitous drop in prices spread like wildfire<br />

throughout town, and the next day trading came to a complete halt, with tra<strong>der</strong>s simply<br />

staring at one another in stunned silence. 71<br />

Still, the bubble had not burst completely, or at least not everywhere. Two days later,<br />

at an auction in Alkmaar — only about 20 miles north of Haarlem — peak prices were<br />

reached for many individual bulbs, as well as for numerous varieties sold in 1000 aas<br />

68 (E.g. <strong>The</strong>uniszoon <strong>van</strong> <strong>der</strong> Lust, 1637)<br />

69 (Krelage, 1942a, p. 80)<br />

70 (Roman, 1637b, p. 17)<br />

71 (Roman, 1637b, p. 17)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 28<br />

quantities. However, that the prices fetched by the pound goods on offer did not appear in<br />

the broadside was published to advertise the auction results. 72 It seems plausible that<br />

these prices had already been affected by collapse of the market in Haarlem. By this<br />

point, moreover, news of the latter had spread to other towns, and bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s<br />

everywhere were girding for the crash. <strong>The</strong> first recorded evidence of a response on the<br />

part of the tra<strong>der</strong>s was a Feb 7 th meeting in Utrecht to decide which representatives to<br />

send to a meeting to be held in Amsterdam on February 23 rd of the trading colleges<br />

throughout Holland.<br />

That Amsterdam meeting included representatives not only from Amsterdam and<br />

Utrecht, but also from Haarlem, Leiden, Delft, Gouda, Alkmaar, Enkhuizen, Medemblik,<br />

Hoorn, and De Streek. 73 In the event, it proved impossible to arrive at a jointly acceptable<br />

solution. <strong>The</strong> final proposal was to honor all contracts signed through November 30,<br />

1636. All those signed December 1 st or later, however, would be canceled if the buyer<br />

announced by March 1637 that he wished to cancel the contract, and paid a buyout fee<br />

(“roucoop,” i.e. regret fee) of 10% of the agreed purchase price. In the latter case, the<br />

seller would retain ownership of the bulbs. 74<br />

Local authorities did not feel bound to sign on to the solution proposed by the<br />

colleges. On March 7, Haarlem officials announced they were inclined to annul all<br />

contracts signed since the bulbs had been planted in September or October. 75 Similarly,<br />

72 (Lijste <strong>van</strong> Eenighe Tulpaen, 1637)<br />

73 <strong>The</strong> tulip colleges of Rotterdam did not send delegates, but announced ahead of time that they would<br />

abide by any solution arrived at during the meeting.<br />

74 (Barckman, 1637)<br />

75 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 51)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 29<br />

the regents of Hoorn instructed their representatives in the States General of Holland to<br />

propose annulling all contracts, to avoid bankrupting buyers who had agreed to high-<br />

priced deals. 76 <strong>The</strong> Alkmaar authorities, on the other hand, recommended on March 14<br />

that all contracts be upheld, and encouraged their deputies the States assembly to<br />

convince the Haarlem representatives to change their mind. 77 By early April, they appear<br />

to have succeeded, as the Haarlem authorities now suggested that contracts agreed to in<br />

the colleges ought to be upheld. 78 Overall, it is clear that local regulation, which had<br />

played no role during the bubble, was not going to have much of an impact on its<br />

resolution either.<br />

Some looked to the provincial authorities for resolution instead. <strong>The</strong> States finally<br />

agreed to address the issue on April 11th. 79 A few days later the Haarlem officials had<br />

changed their mind again, and sent a missive supporting their colleagues from Hoorn in<br />

the effort to have all contracts nullified. <strong>The</strong>y argued that the bulb trade had involved<br />

“purely imaginary value” and hence was noting more than “empty commerce, tending to<br />

divert people and resources from other honest and necessary trades”. Of equal<br />

importance, they emphasized that annulling contracts “would not only preserve many<br />

hundreds of persons of good name and reputation from ruin and scandal”, but also would<br />

not involve anybody outside these circles, thus preserving peace and tranquility. 80 <strong>The</strong><br />

implication that the crisis was both localized and limited is clear.<br />

76 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 52)<br />

77 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 236)<br />

78 (Dash, 1999, p. 182)<br />

79 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 53)<br />

80 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 57-58)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 30<br />

On April 25th the Court of Holland recommended that the States pursue further<br />

inquiries into to the origin and starting date of the bubble, as well as of the sudden price<br />

collapse. Pending a final decision by the States, all contracts were to remain valid, and<br />

the town authorities were to do their best to mediate and negotiate contract disputes.<br />

Although contracts were to remain in force, the Court recommended a moratorium on any<br />

official enforcement of contracts. Two days later, the States of Holland adopted the<br />

Court’s recommendation verbatim. 81 Numerous towns took the moratorium to mean that<br />

they should not allow their officers to intervene on behalf of one party or another to a<br />

dispute by issuing writs, summons, etc., and passed decrees to this effect. 82<br />

In the absence of government involvement, bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s were forced to resolve<br />

contract disputes amongst themselves, as they had been attempting to do all along. <strong>The</strong><br />

first record of a sales contract canceled by mutual consent dates to February 10th. <strong>The</strong><br />

seller accepted a buy-out payment of 160 gulden for a contract that had been worth 1800<br />

gulden. 83 Many contract disputes were, in fact, settled more or less amicably. Some<br />

contracts already contained buyout clauses, often specifying a penalty payment of 10% of<br />

the purchase price. 84 For those that did not, tra<strong>der</strong>s arrived at their own figures, which<br />

were typically lower. One notary certified that buyout rates ranged from 1-5%, with<br />

plenty of buyers in default refusing to make any payment at all. 85<br />

81 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 58-60)<br />

82 (Dash, 1999, p. 188; Posthumus, 1927, p. 61)<br />

83 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 45-46)<br />

84 (Munting, 1696, p. 911)<br />

85 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 70-71)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 31<br />

Many cases appear to have turned on the principle of honoring contracts, rather than<br />

on the sums involved, which were often quite modest compared to each party’s assets.<br />

What appears to have disturbed those involved in complaints most was the breach of<br />

social norms implied by the refusal to abide by a contract. Here, once again, we see the<br />

importance of the social network within which the tulip traded had been embedded. <strong>The</strong><br />

bursting of the bubble was not much of an economic threat, but it did pose a threat to the<br />

strength of the social network. Since the commercial success of the <strong>Dutch</strong> merchant class<br />

relied heavily on social network ties, such a threat could have serious wi<strong>der</strong> implications.<br />

As Goldgar notes, “the tulip crash struck at the heart of a commercial society that by<br />

necessity relied on reputation and mutual credit.” Moreover, reputation and trust were<br />

particularly important in commercial interactions with high levels of uncertainty — not<br />

just tulips, but also the highly profitable exploitation of the East and West Indies. As a<br />

result, “It was this social anxiety, this sense of not having the measure of others, that was<br />

most frightening for contemporaries.” 86 While broken contracts were nothing new, they<br />

had always been the exception. In the aftermath of the tulip bubble, they briefly became<br />

the rule, and that was deeply disconcerting. 87<br />

Conclusion<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> tulip mania of 1636-1637 clearly qualifies as a bubble, in the sense that<br />

prices were not sustained by private estimations of value. Claims that market<br />

fundamentals explain the observed price patterns cannot be sustained, despite their<br />

86 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 267)<br />

87 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 294; cf. Krelage, 1942a, p. 101)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 32<br />

popularity in recent years. Nor do arguments about inadequate government regulation<br />

offer much explanatory leverage. Authorities remained largely uninvolved in the bubble<br />

— although the States did consi<strong>der</strong> taxing tulip profits in 1636-1637 — and they mostly<br />

refused to be drawn into the adjudication of individual cases, at least until a year later. 88<br />

However, this does not mean that there was no regulation: the market was regulated by<br />

the rituals and norms that developed around the tulip trade, as well as by the broa<strong>der</strong><br />

social connections within which it was embedded.<br />

<strong>The</strong> social network that made the bubble possible also was the strongest promoter of<br />

amicable resolutions. As we have seen, contemporary observers often blamed the<br />

problems on a few speculators in pound goods. However, while such speculators clearly<br />

existed, what made them influential was that socially they were almost indistinguishable<br />

from tulip tra<strong>der</strong>s of long standing. Despite what the epigram at the start of this paper<br />

suggests, they could not be neatly separated from such “true” bulb lovers. In the end, it<br />

was the very strength of the social network that tied all bulb tra<strong>der</strong>s together, new and old<br />

alike, that made the bubble possible.<br />

All this suggests that the tulip mania deserves to retain its position as a classic<br />

financial bubble. However, it also indicates that the lessons to be drawn from the bubble<br />

are less about a spectacular rise in prices followed by a collapse, and more about the<br />

social structures within which the market is embedded. <strong>The</strong> collapse of Bernard Madoff’s<br />

investment empire has led many to highlight to the importance of the social connections<br />

that made investors forego due diligence. 89 However, similar problems also arose in the<br />

88 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 224; Posthumus, 1927, pp. 80-81)<br />

89 (E.g. Schweitzer & Shell, 2009)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 33<br />

much more extensive subprime mortgage market, as Lewis shows in his analysis of the<br />

current crisis. Much of his story centers around the degree to which the collapse of the<br />

subprime mortgage edifice was inevitable, foreseeable, and indeed foreseen by some. <strong>The</strong><br />

message is that those who continued to invest in subprime mortgages and the various<br />

<strong>der</strong>ivates thereof were simply stupid. 90<br />

However, one of the key components in the argument is that Moody’s, the rating<br />

company, misvalued collateralized debt obligations constructed from the weakest part of<br />

the mortgage market. Many other actors in the market trusted Moody’s because they had<br />

been working with Moody’s for a long time and had come to trust its judgment. 91 Indeed,<br />

the current crisis reinforces a central lesson from the tulip bubble: the dangers associated<br />

with a relatively small number of key players embedded in a social network that has<br />

developed over a longer period of time, producing network connections in which trust<br />

and judgment have become dissociated from the specific arena in which they developed.<br />

People trusted Moody’s not because they were experts on subprime mortgages, but<br />

because their judgment had proven reliable in other fields. <strong>The</strong> tulip bubble continues to<br />

be rele<strong>van</strong>t, then, not because it shows that there have always been people willing to pay<br />

many times what something is fundamentally worth, but because it demonstrates that<br />

such people tend to be social fools rather than economic idiots.<br />

90 (Lewis, 2008)<br />

91 (Lewis, 2008)


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 34<br />

References<br />

Aitzema, L. v. (1669-1672). Saken <strong>van</strong> Staet en Oorlogh. 's Gravenhage, NL: Johan<br />

Veely, Johan Tongerloo, and Jasper Doll.<br />

Barckman, P. (1637). Copye <strong>van</strong> een notoriael accoordt, ghemaeckt tusschen de<br />

Gecommitteerde <strong>der</strong> Floristen <strong>van</strong> verscheyde Steden. Amsterdam, NL.<br />

Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Welch, I. (1992). A <strong>The</strong>ory of Fads, Fashion,<br />

Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades. Journal of Political<br />

Economy, 100(5), 992-1026.<br />

Dash, M. (1999). <strong>Tulip</strong>omania: <strong>The</strong> Story of the World's Most Coveted Flower and the<br />

Extraordinary Passions It Aroused. New York, NY: Crown Publishers.<br />

De verstoorde en noyt gestorven flora. (1637).<br />

de Vries, J., & <strong>van</strong> <strong>der</strong> Woude, A. (1997). <strong>The</strong> First Mo<strong>der</strong>n Economy: Success, failure,<br />

and perseverance of the <strong>Dutch</strong> economy, 1500-1815. New York, NY: Cambridge<br />

University Press.<br />

French, D. (2006). <strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> Monetary Environment during <strong>Tulip</strong>mania. Quarterly<br />

Journal of Austrian Economics, 9(1), 3-14.<br />

Garber, P. M. (1989). <strong>Tulip</strong>mania. Journal of Political Economy, 97(3), 535-560.<br />

Garber, P. M. (2000). Famous First bubbles: <strong>The</strong> Fundamentals of Early <strong>Mania</strong>s.<br />

Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.<br />

Goldgar, A. (2007). <strong>Tulip</strong>mania: Money, Honor, and Knowledge in the <strong>Dutch</strong> Golden<br />

Age. Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.<br />

Hong, H., Scheinkman, J., & Xiong, W. (2008). Advisors and Asset Prices: A Model of<br />

the Origins of Bubbles. Journal of Financial Economics, 89, 268-287.<br />

Israel, J. I. (1995). <strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> Republic: Its Rise, Greatness, and Fall. Oxford, UK:<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

Kindleberger, C. P., & Aliber, R. Z. (2005). <strong>Mania</strong>s, Panics and Crashes: A History of<br />

Financial Crises (5th ed.). Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.<br />

Krelage, E. H. (1942a). Bloemenspeculatie in Ne<strong>der</strong>land: De Tulpomanie <strong>van</strong> 1636-'37<br />

en de Hyacintenhandel 1720-'36. Amsterdam, NL: P.N. <strong>van</strong> Kampen & Zoon.


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 35<br />

Krelage, E. H. (1942b). De pamfletten <strong>van</strong> den tulpenwindhandel, 1636-1637. 's<br />

Gravenhage, NL: Martinus Nijhoff.<br />

Krelage, E. H. (1946). Drie eeuwen bloembollenexport: De geschiedenis <strong>van</strong> den<br />

bloembollenhandel en <strong>der</strong> Hollandsche bloembollen tot 1938. 's Gravenhage, NL:<br />

Rijksuitgeverij.<br />

Lewis, M. (2008). <strong>The</strong> End. Condé Nast Portfolio(December).<br />

Lijste <strong>van</strong> Eenighe Tulpaen Verkocht aende meest-biedende op den 5. Februari 1637.<br />

(1637). Alkmaar, NL.<br />

Mackay, C. (1932 [1852]). Memoirs of Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the<br />

Madness of Crowds. New York, NY: L.C. Page & Company.<br />

Moggach, D. (1999). <strong>Tulip</strong> Fever. London, UK: Heinemann.<br />

Munting, A. (1696). Naauwkeurige Beschryving <strong>der</strong> Aardgewassen. Leyden / Utrecht,<br />

NL: Pieter <strong>van</strong><strong>der</strong> Aa / François Halma.<br />

Nairn, A. G. M. (2002). Engines That Move Markets: Technology Investing from<br />

Railroads to the Internet and Beyond. New York, NY: Wiley-Academy.<br />

Nocera, J. (2008, October 10). Swept Up by Insanity of Markets. New York Times,<br />

Noordegraaf, L., & Valk, G. (1996). De gave Gods: De pest in Holland <strong>van</strong>af de late<br />

middeleeuwen. Amsterdam, NL: Bert Bakker.<br />

Posthumus, N. W. (1926). De speculatie in tulpen in de jaren 1636 en 1637. Economisch-<br />

Historisch Jaarboek, 12, 3-99.<br />

Posthumus, N. W. (1927). De speculatie in tulpen in de jaren 1636 en 1637 (II).<br />

Economisch-Historisch Jaarboek, 13, 1-85.<br />

Posthumus, N. W. (1934). De speculatie in tulpen in de jaren 1636 en 1637 (III).<br />

Economisch-Historisch Jaarboek, 18, 229-240.<br />

Roman, A. (1637a). Register <strong>van</strong> de Prijsen <strong>der</strong> Bloemen Zijnde de Derde Samen-<br />

spraeck Tusschen Gaergoed ende Waermond, Inhoudende het Vervolgh <strong>van</strong> den<br />

op ende on<strong>der</strong>gangh <strong>van</strong> Flora. Haarlem, NL: Adriaen Roman.<br />

Roman, A. (1637b). Samen-spraeck Tusschen Waermondt Ende Gaergoedt, Nopende de<br />

Opkomste ende On<strong>der</strong>gangh <strong>van</strong> Flora. Haarlem, NL: Adriaen Roman.


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Dutch</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong> <strong>Mania</strong> 36<br />

Roman, A. (1637c). Tweede Samen-spraeck Tusschen Waermondt Ende Gaergoedt,<br />

Zijnde het Vervolgh <strong>van</strong> den op ende on<strong>der</strong>gangh <strong>van</strong> Flora. Haarlem, NL:<br />

Adriaen Roman.<br />

Schama, S. (1988). <strong>The</strong> Embarrassment of Riches: An Interpretation of <strong>Dutch</strong> Culture in<br />

the Golden Age. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.<br />

Schweitzer, M. E., & Shell, G. R. (2009). <strong>The</strong> Bernard Madoff Case: Trust Takes<br />

Another Blow [Electronic Version]. Knowledge@Wharton,<br />

Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational Exuberance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.<br />

<strong>The</strong>uniszoon <strong>van</strong> <strong>der</strong> Lust, S. (1637). Nieu-Iaers Pest-Spiegel waer in te sien is de<br />

Rechtveerdighe Pest-straffe Gods voorghestelt tot opmerck <strong>der</strong> weeldige Ne<strong>der</strong>-<br />

Lan<strong>der</strong>s in dese snoode bedurven Eeuwe. Hoorn, NL: Zacharias Cornelisz.<br />

Thompson, E. A. (2006). <strong>The</strong> <strong>Tulip</strong>mania: Fact or Artifact. Public Choice, 130, 99-114.<br />

Uzzi, B. (1999). Embeddedness in the Making of Financial Capital: How Social<br />

Relations and Networks Benefit Firms Seeking Financing. American Sociological<br />

Review, 64, 481-505.<br />

<strong>van</strong> Wassenaer, N. (1625). Historisch verhael al<strong>der</strong> ghedenck-weerdichste<br />

geschiedenisse. Amsterdam, NL: Jan Evertsz. Cloppenburgh & Jan Janssen.<br />

Velius, T. (1648). Chroniick <strong>van</strong> Hoorn. Hoorn: Isaac Willemsz.<br />

Visscher, R. (1614). Sinnepoppen. Amsterdam, NL: Willem Iansz.<br />

Watts, D. J. (2003). Six Degrees: <strong>The</strong> Science of a Connected Age. New York, NY: W.W.<br />

Norton.<br />

Watts, D. J. (2007). <strong>The</strong> Accidental Influentials. Harvard Business Review, 22-23.<br />

Wild-Animal Spirits: Why Is Finance So Unstable? (2009, 22 January). Economist.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!