26.07.2013 Views

Robin Boadway and Frank Flatters - Andrew Young School of Policy ...

Robin Boadway and Frank Flatters - Andrew Young School of Policy ...

Robin Boadway and Frank Flatters - Andrew Young School of Policy ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

616 / <strong>Robin</strong> <strong>Boadway</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Frank</strong> <strong>Flatters</strong><br />

represented by the utility function u(Xi, Gi/Li) where Xi is the per capita<br />

consumption <strong>of</strong> private goods, Gi is the quantity <strong>of</strong> public sector goods provided in<br />

province i, <strong>and</strong> GiLia is the services <strong>of</strong> the latter. The parameter a is an index <strong>of</strong> the<br />

'publicness' <strong>of</strong> provincial public services <strong>and</strong> can take values 0 a 1. This<br />

formulation allows us to span the spectrum from pure public goods to pure private<br />

goods since these correspond to a = 0 <strong>and</strong> a = 1 respectively.6 The public service<br />

would be 'impure' or 'partially rivalrous' to use Musgrave's (1969) term if a is<br />

between zero <strong>and</strong> unity. Assuming initially that the value <strong>of</strong> output <strong>of</strong> a province<br />

accrues entirely to its own residents, per capita private goods consumption Xi is given<br />

by [fi(Li) - GiLi]. Notice that we are ignoring any activity by the central or federal<br />

government.7<br />

Provincial government behaviour is easy to characterize in this simple model. Each<br />

one is assumed to behave myopically in the sense that it ignores the influence <strong>of</strong> its<br />

actions on migration. This assumption has been used almost universally in the<br />

literature on local public goods,8 <strong>and</strong> as we have mentioned, it does not affect the<br />

results <strong>of</strong> the model. Under this assumption, a provincial government that aims at<br />

maximizing the welfare <strong>of</strong> its citizens will solve the following problem:<br />

Max u[f(L) - GIL, GILa], (1)<br />

G<br />

where we shall follow the convention <strong>of</strong> dropping the provincial subscripts when<br />

analysing the behaviour <strong>of</strong> a representative province.<br />

The first-order condition for this unconstrained maximization problem yields:<br />

L(-a) UG/UX = 1, (2)<br />

where UG <strong>and</strong> ux are the marginal utilities <strong>of</strong> GILa <strong>and</strong> X respectively. If a = 0, this<br />

corresponds to the familiar Samuelson condition that the sum <strong>of</strong> the marginal rates <strong>of</strong><br />

substitution (MRS) equals the MRT (here unity). Similarly, if a = 1 it reduces to the<br />

optimality condition for pure private goods. The solution to (2) for G determines how<br />

provincial output is divided between private <strong>and</strong> public sectors. To characterize a<br />

migration equilibrium, we must examine how per capita utility in a province varies<br />

with population size.<br />

6 This is similar to the technique used by Borcherding <strong>and</strong> Deacon (1972) <strong>and</strong> Bergstrom <strong>and</strong><br />

Goodman (1973) in their empirical studies <strong>of</strong> local public expenditures in the U.S.A. Both papers<br />

found a close to unity. An alternative way to introduce impurity into public goods is to explicitly<br />

include congestion costs. See Buchanan <strong>and</strong> Goetz (1972), <strong>Flatters</strong>, Henderson, <strong>and</strong> Mieszkowski<br />

(1974), <strong>and</strong> Oakl<strong>and</strong> (1972) for examples <strong>of</strong> this approach. The former method is more convenient<br />

for our purposes but both yield qualitatively similar results.<br />

7 The structure <strong>of</strong> this model is similar to that found in much <strong>of</strong> the theoretical literature on the<br />

subject, except for our generalization to allow for impure public goods. See, for example, <strong>Flatters</strong>,<br />

Henderson, <strong>and</strong> Mieszkowski (1974), Stiglitz (1977), <strong>and</strong> the survey in Atkinson <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz<br />

(1980). Other models have used slightly different devices from the diminishing marginal product <strong>of</strong><br />

labour when applied to fixed l<strong>and</strong> to generate diseconomies <strong>of</strong> population increase. Buchanan <strong>and</strong><br />

Goetz (1972) use club goods (see also Henderson, 1974). Starrett (1980) used spatial considerations.<br />

In these alternative models the qualitative results derived in this section continue to hold.<br />

8 Exceptions to this are Boskin (1973), Pauly (1973), <strong>and</strong> the recent paper by Starrett (1980).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!