11.08.2013 Views

A 2 x 2 Game without the Fictitious Play Property - David Levine's ...

A 2 x 2 Game without the Fictitious Play Property - David Levine's ...

A 2 x 2 Game without the Fictitious Play Property - David Levine's ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

146 NOTE<br />

2. FICTITIOUS PLAY<br />

Let N ={1,2}be <strong>the</strong> set of players. The set of strategies of <strong>Play</strong>er i is denoted<br />

by Y i and <strong>the</strong> payoff function of <strong>Play</strong>er i is denoted by u i .Fori ∈ Nlet −i be <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r player (i.e., <strong>Play</strong>er (3 − i)). Let i be <strong>the</strong> set of mixed strategies of <strong>Play</strong>er<br />

i and let U i be <strong>the</strong> payoff function of <strong>Play</strong>er i in <strong>the</strong> mixed extension game.<br />

For i ∈ N and for y i ∈ Y i we denote by ey i ∈ i <strong>the</strong> probability distribution<br />

concentrated on yi . We call eyi a pure strategy and we will identify this pure<br />

strategy with <strong>the</strong> strategy yi whenever it is convenient to do so.<br />

For every sequence (e(t)) ∞ t=1 of pure strategy profiles in Y = Y 1 × Y 2 we<br />

associate a sequence of beliefs f = f (e) = ( f (t)) ∞ t=1 in = 1 × 2 , where<br />

f (t) = (1/t t s=1 e(s) for every t ≥ 1. f i (t) ∈ i is interpreted as <strong>the</strong> belief<br />

of <strong>Play</strong>er −i on <strong>the</strong> (t + 1)th move of <strong>Play</strong>er i. The sequence e = (e(t)) ∞ t=1 is a<br />

fictitious play process if for every player i, ei (t) is a best reply versus f −i (t − 1)<br />

for every t > 1. We say that <strong>the</strong> fictitious play process (e(t)) ∞ t=1 converges to<br />

equilibrium if every limit point of <strong>the</strong> associated belief sequence is an equilibrium<br />

profile. Equivalently, <strong>the</strong> process converges to equilibrium if for every ε>0<br />

<strong>the</strong>re exists an integer T such that f (t) is an ε-equilibrium for all t ≥ T .We<br />

say that G has <strong>the</strong> fictitious play property if every fictitious play process in G<br />

converges to equilibrium.<br />

THE COUNTEREXAMPLE. Let<br />

G =<br />

(0, 1) (0,0)<br />

(0,0) (0,1)<br />

The rows are labeled by a and b so are <strong>the</strong> columns. We proceed to prove that<br />

this game does not have <strong>the</strong> FPP.<br />

Proof. Note that <strong>Play</strong>er 1 is always indifferent between <strong>the</strong> rows. <strong>Play</strong>er 2<br />

chooses a at stage (T + 1) if f 1 1<br />

1 1<br />

a (T )> , he chooses b if f 2 a (T )< , and he is<br />

2<br />

indifferent between <strong>the</strong> two columns when f 1 1<br />

a (T ) = 2 .<br />

Let T0 = S0 = 1. Both players play a at t = 1. We choose integers 1 < T1 <<br />

S1 < T2 < S2 < T3 < ···in a way that is described below. <strong>Play</strong>er 1 plays a for<br />

T2k < t ≤ T2k+1, k ≥ 0. He plays b o<strong>the</strong>rwise. The integers are chosen so that<br />

f 1<br />

a (T2k) = 1 1 , f 4 a (T2k+1) = 3 1 , and f 4 a (Sk) = 1<br />

for every k ≥ 1. Consequently, in<br />

2<br />

a fictitious play process, <strong>Play</strong>er 2 plays a for every S2k < t ≤ S2k+1 for k ≥ 0,<br />

and he plays b o<strong>the</strong>rwise. We show that<br />

2<br />

lim inf fa k→∞ (T2k+2) ≥ 1<br />

<br />

.<br />

Hence <strong>the</strong> sequence of beliefs has a limit point ( f 1 , f 2 ) with f 1<br />

a<br />

. (2.1)<br />

4<br />

= 1<br />

4<br />

and f 2<br />

a<br />

≥ 1<br />

4 .<br />

Note that <strong>the</strong> equilibrium set of <strong>the</strong> game consists of all pairs ( f 1 , f 2 ) such that

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!