24.08.2013 Views

Soft States

Soft States

Soft States

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Introduction<br />

<strong>Soft</strong> <strong>States</strong>, Strong <strong>States</strong> and Development in Africa<br />

EYASU SOLOMON H.<br />

Can be reached at EYASOL1983@AOL.COM<br />

At the outset it is perhaps important to note that over the past twenty years or so African economic<br />

problems have largely been debated in the context of a narrow of managing economies in crisis<br />

rather than in the broader context of “development”. The reasons for this are commonly known and<br />

do not deserve elaboration. However, at the theoretical level the reasons could be understood to<br />

have had something to do with the decline of “development economics” as the sub-discipline of<br />

economics which has born in the forties and fifties to address issues relating to the economic<br />

problems of the then emerging “development economies”. According to Hirschman (1992) the<br />

ideas put forward at that time shared two basic characteristics: (a) they rejected the monoeconomics<br />

claim of the universality of neo-classical economic analysis and hence its direct applicability to<br />

developing countries (due to a number of well known economic features peculiar to these<br />

countries), and (b) they accepted the mutual benefit claim which asserts that the economic relations<br />

between the advanced countries (the colonizers) and the developing countries (the ex-colonies)<br />

could be shaped in such a way as to yield gains for both.<br />

On the basis of the actual development performance of developing countries over the period<br />

1950-1970, which showed, among other things, that the path to development is neither linear nor<br />

smooth, development economics was subjected to two kinds of attack: “The Neo-classical Right<br />

faulted it for having forsaken the true principles of monoeconomics and for having compounded,<br />

through its newfangled policy recommendations, the problem it set out to solve. For the neo-<br />

Marxist, on the other hand, development economics had not gone far enough in its analysis of the<br />

predicament of the poor countries: so serious was their problem pronounced to be that nothing but<br />

total change in their socio-economic structure and their relation to the rich countries could make a<br />

difference; pending such change, so called development policies only created new forms of<br />

exploitation and dependency” (Hirschman, (1982)). This simultaneous attack on development<br />

economics resulted in its decline. The series of political disasters that struck a number of<br />

developing countries since the sixties, ranging from civil wars to the establishment of murderous<br />

authorization regimes, made it difficult for the discipline to recover.<br />

Judging “development economics” by its policy content, however, Sen (1982) noted that the<br />

strategic themes with which it was concerned addressed common problems that still survive despite<br />

the disappointments of the development experience. These strategic themes include late<br />

industrialization, rapid capital accumulation, mobilization of underemployed rural labor and<br />

“planning and economically active state”. A careful analysis of the development record of the<br />

developing countries in terms of the above policy areas over the period 1960-1980 would show that<br />

“both in terms of cases of success and those of failure the traditional wisdom of development<br />

economics is scarcely contradicted”.<br />

The above conclusion by Sen regarding the policy content of traditional “development<br />

economics” inclusive of the central role of the “state” in the process of development are<br />

increasingly being supported by recent evidence on the evaluation of the development experience in<br />

the various parts of the world. Thus, for example, a careful reading of the World Bank’s (1993)<br />

East Asian Miracle Report shows that indeed the East Asian state was central to bringing abou the<br />

miraculous performance of these countries. Moreover, after nearly two decades of advocating a<br />

minimalist role for the state in “economic management”, the World bank in its 1997 report argues<br />

for an impossibility theorem regarding the role of the state in economic and social development. In<br />

the words of its President the World Bank notes that without “an effective state, sustainable<br />

development, both economic and social, is impossible” (World Bank, 1997: iii).<br />

The major limitation of traditional development economics was its “insufficient recognition that<br />

economic growth was no more than a means to some other objectives”. Thus, for example, in terms<br />

PDF created with pdfFactory trial version www.pdffactory.com


of capability approach to development as articulated by Sen and operationalised by the UNDP<br />

Human Development Reports, if “the government of a poor developing country is keen to raise the<br />

level of health and the expectation of life, then it would be pretty daft to try to achieve this through<br />

raising its income per head, rather than going directly for these objectives through public policy and<br />

social change”. This is the crux of the role of the state in the development process. The question<br />

remains, however, what type of state? And the literature is full of various types1.<br />

The objective of this portion is to provoke further discussion on the “state” in the context of<br />

“development” in Africa. The rest of the portion is organized as follows. In section two, we present<br />

the original logic behind the coinage of the term “soft state”. We note in passing that the “strong<br />

state” can be defined by default as the opposite of the “soft state”. The original formulation of the<br />

term was undertaken in the context of development. Since then a search for a “developmental state”<br />

was mounted. Once again in the context of “developmental achievements” a recent model for such<br />

a “developmental state” was proposed. We review the elements of this model in section three. By<br />

definition a “developmental state” is taken to be a “strong state”, and given the developmental<br />

performance of the recent past the model is base on Asian experience. In section four we test this<br />

model with respect to Africa. In section five we present the most recent World bank position of the<br />

role of the “state” in development and its model for the “right kind of state”. Section six concludes.<br />

The <strong>Soft</strong> State<br />

Myrdal (1968) first coined the term “soft state” in the context of development in his monumental<br />

work on post-independence South Asia. In that context Myrdal characterized Asian states as “soft”<br />

with reference to the general societal “indiscipline” compare to the emergence of the modern state<br />

in Europe. According to Myrdal (1968: 896) “soft states” is a characterization of social reality<br />

meaning that “national governments require extraordinarily little of their citizens. There are few<br />

obligations either to do things in the interest of the community or to avoid actions opposed to that<br />

interest. Even those obligations that do exist are enforced inadequately if at all. This low level of<br />

social discipline is one of the most fundamental differences between South Asian countries today<br />

and Western countries at the beginning of their industrialization”.<br />

A correct reading of Myrdal would show that the social reality of the “soft state” at that particular<br />

point in time was a result of a historical process. To appreciate this we note the following sequence<br />

in the logic of the coinage of the term (Myrdal, 1986:895-900):<br />

(i) In an original setting of village life there existed no difference between social life in preindustrial<br />

European villages and those of developing countries where societies had<br />

“widely ramifying and stratified systems of obligations defining the duties of different<br />

categories of village inhabitants” regarding the construction and maintenance of<br />

infrastructure, the maintenance of local security and defence against aggressors. The use<br />

of land and employment of labor are similarly regulated by custom. These social<br />

relationships were defined in terms of relations between individuals and families “rather<br />

than in terms of a common community interests”;<br />

(ii) The long-term trends of European social relations have been such that they gravitated<br />

toward “the perfection of these systems of obligations and their transformation from a<br />

network of individual relationships into obligations to the community”. Similar long<br />

term trends that could have been observed about village communities in less developed<br />

countries were essentially pre-empted by colonialism which “led to the decay of the<br />

ancient village organization without the creation of a substitute”;<br />

(iii) The less developed countries emerged as a result of a long struggle against a colonial<br />

state and the “liberation movements were rebellions against authority, and the<br />

disobedience to authority was their weapon”. Thus, “disobedience” and “non-co-<br />

PDF created with pdfFactory trial version www.pdffactory.com


operation” were natural forms of protest and defence “against the enforced colonial<br />

power structure”;<br />

(iv) The legacy of the liberation struggle “is a set of anarchic attitudes with an ideological<br />

and emotional force deriving from memories of resistance against the colonial power. In<br />

the newly independent countries, this attitude is now being turned against their own<br />

authorities”.<br />

The above, then, is the logic behind the origin of the term “soft state”. The logic is based on a<br />

reading of the immediate post-independence South Asian experience, but could certainly read as<br />

referring to that of Africa. Central to the analysis, however, is the observation tha the “historical<br />

trends” of natural emergence of a “strong state” in developing countries, where obligations towards<br />

the community are codified as a natural time trend from village based cooperative attitudes, were<br />

derailed by the “colonial encounter”. Like other counterfactuals it will be extremely difficult to<br />

conjuncture whether the term “soft state” would have ever been coined had there been so such<br />

encounter2.<br />

Another important dimension of the above type of analysis informing the coinage of the term, and<br />

indeed its substantive descriptive content, is the possibility of an appreciation of the nature of the<br />

origin of the causal factors behind the dismal development performance of Africa in the recent past.<br />

As noted by a number of contributions to the vast literature on adjustment in Africa, most of<br />

African authors argue in terms of external causation of the continent’s malaise. In contrast, most<br />

non-African authors argue in terms of policy mistakes committed by African “soft states”3.<br />

Developmental <strong>States</strong><br />

Times, of course, have changed since Myrdal wrote his perceptive piece on the political factors in<br />

the process of development policy making. The “soft states” of that time have become the<br />

“developmental states” of recent times. In a contribution Leftwich (1995) proposed what he termed<br />

a “model” for the “developmental state” drawing largely from very recent Asian development<br />

experience. The set of developing countries used by Leftwich is defined by achieving a per capita<br />

growth rate in excess of 4% per annum over the period 1965-1990 and includes South Korea<br />

(7.1%), Taiwan (7%), Singapore (6.5%), China (5.8%), Indonesia ((4.5%), Thailand (4.4%) and<br />

Malaysia (4.4%), in addition to Botswana (8.4%). The objective of the contribution by Leftwich, as<br />

declared in the title of the paper, is to bring “politics back” into development discourse in the sense<br />

that “the single most important factor in generating sustained developmental momentum has been<br />

the presence in each of a particular type of state, a ‘developmental state’, which must be understood<br />

politically” (Leftwich, 1995: 401).<br />

According to Leftwich (1995:401) a developmental state is defined as a state “whose politics<br />

have concentrated sufficient power, autonomy and capacity at the center to shape, pursue and<br />

encourage the achievement of explicit developmental; objectives, whether by establishing and<br />

promoting the conditions and direction of economic growth, or by organizing it directly, or a<br />

varying combination f both”. On the basis of such a definition, and on the basis of the recent<br />

development experience of East Asian countries, Leftwich offered six major descriptive<br />

components to define a developmental state. These can be summarized in the following.<br />

• The character of the developmental elite: there exists a core of developmentally-determined<br />

senior politicians and bureaucrats “close to the executive head of government who was instrumental<br />

in establishing the developmental regime and its culture”. The core elites are characterized by their<br />

intimacy and linkage with their bureaucratic and political components and by being relatively noncorrupt.<br />

• The relative autonomy of the state: which is defined as the ability of the state “to achieve relative<br />

independence from the demanding clamor of special interests” and its ability to override these<br />

PDF created with pdfFactory trial version www.pdffactory.com


interests when it is necessary to do so. Autonomy in this sense does not mean isolation, but rather<br />

“embedded autonomy” in the sense of Evans (1989) where the state forges dense ties with various<br />

actors with the objective of facilitating its economic co-ordination function and its ability of<br />

implementation of developmental objectives. The autonomy of the state is found to be a positive<br />

function of regional competition and external threat, the seizure of power by a modernizing<br />

developmental elite, the dominance of a single party and the inflow of substantial amounts of<br />

foreign aid, loans and private investment.<br />

• The economic bureaucracy: means the specific institutions charged with the responsibility of<br />

managing the interaction between the state and the economy. In shaping development policy, this<br />

economic bureaucracy is found to have real power and authority, to be technically competent and<br />

insulated<br />

• The civil society: by civil society is meant the “web of all privately-organized interests and<br />

groups, above the family level but below that of the state”. Developmental states are said to have<br />

emerged in social contexts where civil society has been crushed or was weak to start with. Starting<br />

from an initial condition, civil societies have been controlled by t he use of internal security<br />

legislation and agencies, secret police and party organizations.<br />

• The non-state economic interests: developmental states are found to have consolidated their<br />

power and autonomy prior to the emergence of influential national or foreign capital and other<br />

economic interests. Subsequently, the state played a major role in encouraging the emergence and<br />

growth of private economic institutions and in shaping their scope and focus of activity in the light<br />

of the articulated development goals.<br />

• The performance criteria: developmental states are found to have been characterized by “brutal<br />

suppression of civil rights”, wide measure of legitimacy and sustained record of delivering<br />

developmental goods.<br />

On the basis of the above characterization of a developmental state Leftwich (1995: 421)<br />

concludes that few “societies in the modern world will make speedy transitions from poverty<br />

without states which approximate this model of a developmental state (ideally, but not necessarily,<br />

the democratic kind)…Contrary to the current orthodoxy, development requires not less state but<br />

better state action, and this is more likely from developmental states. Thus calls for governance, or<br />

democratic governance, which focus on administrative, judicial or electoral good practice, entirely<br />

miss the point that such virtues can only be instituted and sustained by politics”.<br />

While one may agree with the general conclusion of Leftwich that effecting development requires<br />

more, rather than less, “state”, the general characterization of the model of the “developmental<br />

state” is problematic. The inclusion of Botswana in the set of countries on the basis of which the<br />

characterization was undertaken could be taken as a bid to be “statically correct”, given that the<br />

basic emphasis was on “development” performance where in this case development is equated with<br />

per capita economic growth.<br />

The first three components of the model are clearly related bureaucratic structures of the “state”<br />

while the last one is an outcome variable. The “civil society” and “non-state economic interests”<br />

components could be taken as representing “political stability” factors. Assuming that such<br />

classification is correct, the question arises as to whether there existed a difference between African<br />

and Asian states during the period considered by Leftwich.<br />

The Developmental State: A Test<br />

Recent information made available by Mauro (1995) enables us to test Leftwich’s model of the<br />

developmental state. Masuro was able to compile the relevant information about variables relevant<br />

to our undertaking from the Business International (BI) flies for the period 1980-1983. BI used to<br />

compute indices on country risks of interests to foreign investors. The indices fall between zero and<br />

unity with a high figure implying that the country has “good” institutions. Using detailed<br />

PDF created with pdfFactory trial version www.pdffactory.com


information, Mauro calculated the period averages for the indices for each country. Mauro (1995:<br />

684) provides the original BI definitions of the relevant indicators as follows:<br />

• Political change: in the institutional sense: which asks about the “possibility that the institutional<br />

framework will be changed within the forecast period by elections or other means”;<br />

• Political stability in the social sense: which asks about the “degree to which the orderly political<br />

process tends to disintegrate or become violent”;<br />

• Political change: in the political sense: and asks about the likelihood “that the opposition will<br />

come to power during the forecast period”;<br />

• Relationship with neighboring countries: and asks about political, economic and commercial<br />

relations with; neighbors “that may affect companies doing business in the country”;<br />

• Terrorism: asks about the degree “to which individuals and businesses are subject to acts of<br />

terrorism”;<br />

• Legal system and the judiciary: and asks about the “efficiency and integrity of the legal<br />

environment as it affects business, particularly foreign firms”;<br />

• Bureaucracy and red tape: asks about the “regulatory environment foreign firms must face when<br />

seeking approvals and permits and the degree to which it represents an obstacle to business”;<br />

• Corruption: and asks about the “degree to which business transactions involves corruption or<br />

questionable payments”.<br />

Mauro aggregates political stability factors in one index, given the high correlation between the<br />

elements and aggregates the “efficiency of the judiciary”, “red tape” and “corruption” into a<br />

bureaucratic efficiency” index. It is these aggregate indices that we shall use in testing Leftwich<br />

“developmental state” model.<br />

Appendix tables (A.1) and (A.2) provide the relevant details for the African (13 countries) and<br />

Asian (13 countries) samples for which information is available. For the whole sample of 68<br />

countries for which relevant data is reported by Mauro, Singapore is found to be the country with<br />

best state institutions scoring the highest score of 10 for all indices.<br />

Table (1) reports our results of testing the means of the relevant indices for the African and Asian<br />

samples where figures between brackets are standard deviations. We note that in the Asian sample,<br />

and except for China, all of Leftwich’s Asian states are included; while in the African sample<br />

Botswana is not included due to lack of information4.<br />

Table (1): Developmental State Indices: Africa vs. Asia<br />

Index Africa Asia Absolute t-value*<br />

1. Efficiency of the Judiciary 5.18 (2.13) 6.79 (2.43) 2.61<br />

2. Red Tape 4.80 (1.92) 5.87 (2.36) 1.79<br />

3. Corruption 5.16 (2.36) 5.62 (2.46) 0.73<br />

4. Bureaucratic Efficiency 5.23 (1.63) 6.09 (2.32) 1.50<br />

Political Stability 6.71 (1.37) 7.59 (1.45) 1.82<br />

Source: Mauro (1995: appendix 3).<br />

*The critical t-values are 1.71 for the 5% level of significance and 2.49 for the 1% level of significance<br />

From the above table and at the 5% level of significance the difference between Asian and<br />

African states is found to be significant as relates to the “efficiency of the judiciary” and “red tape”<br />

with Asian states having “better” institutions. Regarding “corruption” there existed in the 1980s no<br />

significant difference between the two regions. Looking at the composite index of “bureaucratic<br />

efficiency”, the table shows that at the 5% level of significance there does not seem to have existed<br />

a significant difference between the “state” in the two regions. This is both interesting and<br />

significant. The significant difference between the two regions at the 5% level is found regarding<br />

PDF created with pdfFactory trial version www.pdffactory.com


the “political stability” factor where Asian clearly enjoyed much more stable political environment.<br />

Thus, a further composite index representing Lefteich’s model where the political stability factor is<br />

given more weight could result in a ranking consistent with his thesis.<br />

Moving to the 1% level of significance the only remaining significant difference between the two<br />

regions is found in the “efficiency of the judiciary”. For all other factors inclusive of political<br />

stability, no significant difference could be detected.<br />

Judging the African state by world standards, however, could support Leftwich’s model of the<br />

“developmental state”. Table (2) presents our results in this respect where a sample of 68 countries<br />

for which information is available.<br />

Table (2): Developmental State Indices: Africa vs. The World<br />

Index Africa The World Absolute t-value*<br />

1. Efficiency of the Judiciary 5.18 (2.13) 6.97 (2.36) 3.83<br />

2. Red Tape 4.80 (1.92) 6.03 (2.33) 2.67<br />

3. Corruption 5.16 (2.36) 6.81 (2.54) 3.40<br />

4. Bureaucratic Efficiency 5.23 (1.63) 6.64 (2.18) 3.18<br />

5. Political Stability 6.71 (1.37) 7.52 (1.39) 2.27<br />

Source: Mauro (1995: appendix 3)<br />

*The critical t-values are 1.65 for the 5% level of significance and 2.33 for the 1% level of significance.<br />

As is clear from the table the institutions of the state in Africa are significantly lacking compared<br />

to the average equality prevailing at he level of the world at the 5% level of significance.<br />

Surprisingly, however, at the 1% level of significance Africa is found not to be significantly<br />

different in terms of “political stability”.<br />

The Right Kind of <strong>States</strong><br />

In the context of Africa and in the eclipse of serious minded discourse on development proper, a<br />

search for the right kind of the “state” was mounted. The search was for the right kind of the state<br />

that will be capable to implement the “adjustment programs” of the World bank/IMF variety. After<br />

a brief period of flirting with desirability of instituting a “minimalist” state that does not do<br />

anything apart from ensuring “peace and security” and guarding “property rights”, the pendulum<br />

has quickly shifted to looking for a “quasi-activist state” that could do the things that it is better<br />

suited to do compare to the private agents in the economy. The objective circumstances that led to<br />

this shift are analyzed by Clapham (1996:814) who notes that it was no “wonder that the<br />

‘monoeconomics’ which had helped to promote the drive for structural adjustment should be<br />

supplemented by a ‘monopolitics’ which saw in Western liberal democracy a universally applicable<br />

formula for good government accompanied by economic euccess”.<br />

This search for the “right kind of state” gave rise to “political conditionality” in aid programs<br />

which was added to the technical “economic conditionality” of the original adjustment programs.<br />

According to Calpham (1996) the newly found political conditionality revolved around three major<br />

concerns of effective government, accountability and human rights. The content of the first<br />

concern, which is amenable to imposition by multilateral institutions, argues for the creation of an<br />

“effective government machinery, which would replace the ‘soft, fat’ state with its inflated<br />

bureaucracy geared to the needs of political patronage, by a ‘lean hard’ state which employed the<br />

limited staff needed to provide essential services within a privately managed capitalist economy”.<br />

The World bank (1997: 25-28) elaborates a framework to explore the practical implications of<br />

this political conditionality in establishing the “right kind of state”. The framework is based on a<br />

classification of the two major functions of the state (i.e. addressing market failure and improving<br />

equity) “along a continuum, from activities that will not be undertaken at all without state<br />

intervention to activities in which the state plays an activist role in co-ordinating markets and<br />

PDF created with pdfFactory trial version www.pdffactory.com


distributing assets”. The continuum goes from the minimalist functions of the state (of providing<br />

pure public goods: defence, law and order, property rights, macroeconomic management, public<br />

health, antipoverty programs and disaster relief) to activist functions (co-ordinating private sector<br />

activities and asset distribution). The intermediate functions include addressing externalities<br />

(provision of basic education and environmental protection), regulating monopoly (utility<br />

regulation and antitrust policy), overcoming imperfect information (provision of insurance,<br />

regulation of financial markets and consumer protection) and providing social insurance (pensions,<br />

family allowances and unemployment insurance).<br />

On the basis of the above framework a two part strategy for establishing the “right kind of state is<br />

proposed. The two elements of the strategy are “matching the states role to its capability” and<br />

“raising the state’s effectiveness by reinvigorating public institutions”. The capability of the state is<br />

defined as “its ability to undertake and promote collective action efficiently”, while the<br />

effectiveness of the state is defined as the “result of using the capability to meet society’s demand<br />

for the” collective goods involved.<br />

Along the continuum of functions, states can be classified given their capabilities: those with low<br />

capability need to focus on basic functions of providing pure public goods. Moreover, given<br />

capability, the state’s effectiveness requires exploring alternative instruments for performing<br />

functions. Thus, for example, in the provision of basic services “it is not obvious that the state must<br />

be only provider, or a provider at all”. The relative strengths of markets, civil society and state<br />

agencies need to be carefully considered prior to taking a decision on the provision of such<br />

services.<br />

The second part of the proposed strategy is concerned with reinvigorating the state’s capability.<br />

The central concept in this component is that improvements in the capability of state can only be<br />

achieved if the “incentives under which states and state institutions operate. The key is to find rules<br />

and norms that create incentives for state agencies and officials to act in the collective interest,<br />

while restraining arbitrary action”. The elements involved for bringing this about are not much<br />

different from those in Leftwich model of the “developmental state”: efficient judiciary, competent<br />

bureaucracy and an ability to resolve non-state economic interests.<br />

A careful reading to the requirement of the “right kind of state” will show that it is perhaps early<br />

days yet to celebrate a fundamental change in the ruling quasi-development paradigm of the 1980s<br />

which was associated with the resurgence of neoclassical economics. While the model of the right<br />

kind of state acknowledges the market failure facets with which “development economics” was<br />

concerned, and on the basis of which an active role for the state in the development process was<br />

envisaged at the time, it uses as its reference for judging the capability of the state a minimaliststate<br />

position rather an objective of development to be achieved during a planning horizon.<br />

We also note that the “right kind of state” does not have to be democratic: it only needs to be<br />

efficient in terms of serving a “public interest” the mechanism of its definition is left vague and<br />

unspecified. Being silent about this could be taken to be agreeing with the general thrust of<br />

Leftwich’s proposition that “voting can be bad for your wealth”!<br />

Concluding Remarks<br />

The above analysis of the issues involved regarding the role of the state in the development<br />

process should serve to demonstrate that we are still some way to go on agreeing on the<br />

fundamentals. Central to the issues is the political and social mechanisms required for defining the<br />

“public interest” in a given social and historical context. The “developmental state” model cal<br />

clearly sustain “non-democratic” forms of governance where a “developmentally committed” elite<br />

can define the “public interest”. The political process of generating such a model has been tried in<br />

Africa with little to show for it. One possible explanation is that because the continent at the time<br />

was far removed from the “strategic hot spots” of the cold war, it was easy to destabilize the<br />

creation of the “developmental state”. Such an explanation is clearly based on the “external<br />

PDF created with pdfFactory trial version www.pdffactory.com


influence” school of explaining the dismal performance of the continent. However, it is not devoid<br />

of merits, given that there was no significant difference between Africa and Asia on the basis of the<br />

components of the “developmental state” at the beginning of the 1980s.<br />

At the other extreme, the possibility of the emergence of a “developmental state” from within the<br />

African society has been presented by Mkandawire (1992) who was concerned with a democratic<br />

support for a genuine development strategy on the continent. According to his analysis, some “of<br />

the coalition which have been construed to lie behind certain policies and which would block<br />

reform do not in fact exist, and, if they do exist, they are constituted by members with multiple<br />

affiliations who will be supportive of a whole range of options other than those which can be read<br />

off from the deterministic specification of political alliances in Africa” (Mkandawire, 1992: 311).<br />

The empirical evidence on which the above conclusion is based has to do with the political<br />

resistance to the social impact of the adjustment programs implemented on the continent. This<br />

political vitality is interpreted as reflecting a call for “egalitarian” development by all newly<br />

constituted parties in the continent. Mkandawire, however, is mindful that this democratic crave for<br />

egalitarian development could once again be destabilized from outside5. This is not surprising, for<br />

Mkandawire is an African development economist, who could be classified as a believer in<br />

“conspiracy theory”.<br />

End Notes<br />

1. Fr examples of political economy classification of “states” see, for example, Lal and Myint<br />

(1996): autonomous (benevolent dictactor or predatory) and factional (oligarchic or<br />

democratic). These classifications are based on the “new” political economy by, which is<br />

meant “the application of the economic principle to areas, which were previously<br />

considered the province of political science”. The new political economy comprises two<br />

schools: social choice and public choice schools. Mcguire and Olson (1996) provide a<br />

political invisible hand that works across the classification of states: autocratic or<br />

democratic. For an earlier application to Africa see Bates (1981), and for a recent one see<br />

Azam (1995).<br />

2. A novel reinterpretation of Africa’s colonial history and its implication for the formation of<br />

the African state is provided by Mamdani (1996).<br />

3. for an excellent summary of the various positions, see Calpham (1996).<br />

4. For a comparison of Africa and Asia on the basis of economic policy stance see Elbadawi<br />

(1996) where Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand are used as a frontier of policy stance and<br />

where the budget deficit, the real rate of interest, the inflation rate and the parallel exchange<br />

rate are used as the policy stance indicators. This macro aspect can be related to the<br />

performance criteria of Leftwich.<br />

5. He notes that the “big question is whether the international political and economic climate<br />

will be supportive of both the quest for democratic governance and the egalitarian strategies<br />

of adjustment and growth”.<br />

PDF created with pdfFactory trial version www.pdffactory.com

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!