25.12.2013 Views

The impact of Iran's subsidy reform on households ... - Filebox

The impact of Iran's subsidy reform on households ... - Filebox

The impact of Iran's subsidy reform on households ... - Filebox

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>households</strong>: Evidence<br />

from survey data<br />

Djavad Salehi-Isfahani<br />

Virginia Tech, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Brookings Instituti<strong>on</strong>, and the Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Forum<br />

Bryce Wils<strong>on</strong> Stucki<br />

Virginia Tech<br />

September 2013<br />

Joshua Deutschmann<br />

Virginia Tech<br />

Abstract<br />

In December 2010 Iran launched an ambitious Targeted Subsidy Reform program<br />

that raised prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bread and energy products by 2 to 22 times. Unlike <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in<br />

other countries, which are <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten met with protests and are sometimes aband<strong>on</strong>ed, Iran’s<br />

program appears to have survived its first 18 m<strong>on</strong>ths without major incidents. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> key<br />

to the program’s success are cash transfers electr<strong>on</strong>ically deposited in individual family<br />

bank accounts <strong>on</strong> a regular basis. We use survey data for the first three m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> to study participati<strong>on</strong> in and the <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cash program during<br />

its early phase. We find that, c<strong>on</strong>trary to expectati<strong>on</strong>s, rural families that had less<br />

access to banks participated in greater numbers, though the poorest income decile, like<br />

the highest, participated least. Our findings suggest that during its early phase the<br />

program was pro-poor and pro-equity. We estimate that the poverty rate during this<br />

phase declined by about 5 percentage points, mostly in rural areas, and indicators <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

inequality registered declines.<br />

Keywords: Iran, Subsidy <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Income distributi<strong>on</strong>, Poverty, Cash transfer<br />

∗ We are grateful to the Statistical Center <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran for providing us with the survey data and to participants<br />

in the World Bank seminar, September 26, 2012, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC, for helpful comments.


1 Introducti<strong>on</strong><br />

Before Iran implemented its ambitious <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> program in December 2010, it was<br />

the world’s most wasteful user <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> energy. It topped the list <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 37 developing countries that<br />

subsidized energy, according to the Internati<strong>on</strong>al Energy Agency and the IMF (Internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

Energy Agency 2010; IMF 2013). In 2010, Iran spent an estimated $70 billi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> energy<br />

subsidies, about twice the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its government budget and <strong>on</strong>e-fifth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its GDP. 1 Other<br />

subsidies, such as bread and medicine, added another $5 billi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> distorti<strong>on</strong>s resulting from decades <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsidizing energy are resp<strong>on</strong>sible for making<br />

Iran into <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the world’s least energy efficient ec<strong>on</strong>omies. Whereas in 1980 Iran used<br />

about 137 kg <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oil equivalent energy per $1000 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> GDP, two decades later it used twice as<br />

much. During the same period and resp<strong>on</strong>ding to higher energy prices, the United States<br />

reduced its energy intensity by 45% and the world by 23% (World Bank WDI Data Bank).<br />

In 2009 Iran used two-and-a-half times as much energy to produce a unit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> GDP as Turkey,<br />

a country with a similar GDP per capita.<br />

Awareness about the need to end the subsidies had been increasing in Iran for many<br />

years, both <strong>on</strong> account <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its wastefulness and inequity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> top income decile benefited<br />

more than 3 times as much as the bottom decile from energy subsidies. Different Iranian<br />

administrati<strong>on</strong>s debated and even made partial attempts to end the subsides, but in the<br />

end it was the populist Ahmadinejad administrati<strong>on</strong>, motivated in part by the inequity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the energy subsidies, that took decisive acti<strong>on</strong> to end the subsidies. In December 2010, the<br />

government launched an ambitious Targeted Subsidy Reform program (TSR) that raised<br />

prices for fuel and bread by 2 to 11 times. Unlike <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in other countries, which<br />

are <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten met with social protests and subsequently aband<strong>on</strong>ed, Iran’s program appears to<br />

have survived its first two years without major incidents 2<br />

Energy subsidies are popular and easy to implement, especially in oil producing countries<br />

where the government does not incur outlays, but removing them is very difficult. Most<br />

country efforts to remove subsidies have been met with protests and riots, and subsequently<br />

aband<strong>on</strong>ed. Recently Nigeria, Bolivia, and Pakistan have made unsuccessful attempts at<br />

energy price increases; in each case, price changes were either quickly rolled back or never<br />

implemented. In Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, where earlier attempts at <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> had been met with<br />

1 Estimates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> energy subsidies are based <strong>on</strong> the internati<strong>on</strong>al price <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oil and natural gas because they<br />

measure the opportunity cost <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> selling energy domestically, not expenditures recorded in the government<br />

budget. As a result they can vary from <strong>on</strong>e source to another. This also explains why the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

is larger than the total government budget.<br />

2 For a detailed account <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program see Guillaume et al. 2011; see also Salehi-Isfahani 2011, Atashbar<br />

2012, Hassanzadeh 2012, and Nili 2010 (in Persian).<br />

1


iots and, in <strong>on</strong>e instance, a government collapse (Bac<strong>on</strong> and Kojima 2006, Beat<strong>on</strong> and<br />

L<strong>on</strong>toh 2010), the government changed course in 2005 and s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>tened price increases with cash<br />

transfers to the poor, a crucial difference. Iran’s program is noteworthy for two reas<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the price adjustment and its innovative cash transfer program. Price increases<br />

ranged from 2 to 22 times, posing a big shock to c<strong>on</strong>sumer budgets and threatening a large<br />

political backlash at a time when the government was mired in the nuclear dispute with the<br />

West, and had lost much <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political support in the aftermath <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>troversial re-electi<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> President Ahmadinejad.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> key to the program’s success in making the mammoth adjustments in prices without<br />

political backlash was a cash transfer program under which the government electr<strong>on</strong>ically<br />

deposited into individual bank accounts 445,000 rials per m<strong>on</strong>th (about 45 or 90 USD PPP<br />

in 2010). In 2010 this was about 28% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median per capita expenditures and greater<br />

than the m<strong>on</strong>thly expenditures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2.8 milli<strong>on</strong> Iranians. 3 It was about 10% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the m<strong>on</strong>thly<br />

wage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an unskilled worker, so an unskilled worker with a family <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 4 would be receiving a<br />

transfer equal to about 40% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> his or her m<strong>on</strong>thly wage.<br />

Despite its innovative design and apparent initial success, narrowly defined, the TSR<br />

has not yet been studied rigorously. Media reports have been generally critical, reflecting<br />

opini<strong>on</strong>s expressed by upper income Iranians who stood to lose in the bargain, blaming<br />

the program for inflati<strong>on</strong>, unemployment, and rising inequality. Our findings questi<strong>on</strong><br />

these popular percepti<strong>on</strong>s. But, we should hasten to add that this paper is not an overall<br />

evaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> program. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> survey data available to us covers <strong>on</strong>ly the<br />

first three m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the implementati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> TSR, which is not l<strong>on</strong>g enough to assess its full<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> inflati<strong>on</strong>, unemployment, ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, poverty and inequality. Even with<br />

more data an accurate assessment may not be possible because other events have intervened<br />

since the TSR program went into effect. Intensificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> internati<strong>on</strong>al sancti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e<br />

year after the start <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s caused the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rial to drop, adding to the<br />

inflati<strong>on</strong>ary effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s and dealing a serious blow to output. Macroec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

mismanagement has independently affected Iran’s ec<strong>on</strong>omy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> low-cost housing program<br />

known as Maskan Mehr, worth about $20 billi<strong>on</strong> and a major source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> government deficit,<br />

has pushed inflati<strong>on</strong> bey<strong>on</strong>d what the TSR would have caused. We may never be able<br />

to disentangle the <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR <strong>on</strong> key macroec<strong>on</strong>omic variables such as inflati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

unemployment and ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> TSR does appear, however, to have restrained c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> energy products, <strong>on</strong>e<br />

3 Compare this to 22% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor <strong>households</strong> in the Ind<strong>on</strong>esian cash transfer program following<br />

energy <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> (Camer<strong>on</strong> and Shah 2011).<br />

2


<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its main objectives. According to <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficial reports, the year following the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> demand<br />

for most energy products dropped – fuel oil by 36.4 percent, petrol by 5.6 percent, diesel by<br />

9.8 percent and kerosene by 2.9 percent (Hassanzadeh 2012). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se are significant savings<br />

especially when compared to the c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> growth rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about 10 percent per year<br />

for energy products in the past. Demand for utilities also changed directi<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> electricity and water declined by 1.7 and 6 percent, respectively, as did natural gas<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> by <strong>households</strong>, 1.5 percent, but demand for natural gas rose overall by 6.1<br />

percent, perhaps because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> planned shifts in c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> from oil products to natural gas,<br />

particularly in power generati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In this paper we focus <strong>on</strong> the short term <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program <strong>on</strong> household welfare.<br />

We trace how the cash transfer flowed to poor and rich <strong>households</strong>, to rural and urban<br />

families, and to those living in developed and disadvantaged provinces in the immediate<br />

m<strong>on</strong>ths following the program. We also measure how higher energy prices affected direct<br />

household expenditures <strong>on</strong> energy products. Understanding the short term distributi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> price <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s is important because it is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten what <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s to the welfare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> low<br />

income <strong>households</strong> in the first few weeks or m<strong>on</strong>ths that determine their survival politically.<br />

Riots and political backlash in the early stages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten what kills them.<br />

In the short term, before <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> has worked its way through the price system,<br />

governments must be able to answer key questi<strong>on</strong>s such as: Who are the winners and losers<br />

from the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>? What level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> compensati<strong>on</strong> enough to outweigh the political and social<br />

cost <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the price shock? Most governments hesitate to take up <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> because they<br />

cannot c<strong>on</strong>vince the lower income groups that they stand to gain from <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

benefits from reducing budget deficits or redirecting <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditures to health and<br />

educati<strong>on</strong> do not materialize quickly enough for the average pers<strong>on</strong> to accept the pain <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

higher prices. From the political ec<strong>on</strong>omy point <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> view establishing trust during the early<br />

phase regarding the government’s intenti<strong>on</strong> to redistribute the savings back to some or all<br />

income groups is the most important determinant <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> program success. This is the less<strong>on</strong><br />

from the cash transfer scheme in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran.<br />

We use data from the 2010 (corresp<strong>on</strong>ding to Iranian year 1389) expenditure survey,<br />

which covers the first three m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program (December 19, 2010 to March 20, 2011)<br />

to follow the pace <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> implementati<strong>on</strong> and program participati<strong>on</strong>, as well as the program’s<br />

geographic coverage (rural and urban by province) and its <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> poverty and inequality.<br />

We find that the payment mechanism, though it relied <strong>on</strong> the modern banking system,<br />

generally did not discriminate against people with less access to banks, such as the rural<br />

poor or the inhabitants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> disadvantaged provinces. During the first three m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

3


program we notice that rural families were more likely to be receiving cash transfers than<br />

urban families. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> lowest and highest deciles were less likely to participate than middle<br />

income families. Finally, by March 2011 (Esfand 1389) inequality and the incidence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

poverty had declined appreciably compared to previous year.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remainder <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this paper is organized as follows. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> next secti<strong>on</strong> provides a descripti<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR’s implementati<strong>on</strong>. Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 discusses the circumstance under which<br />

the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> was initiated and implemented. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 describes the cash transfer program<br />

and its implementati<strong>on</strong>. Secti<strong>on</strong> 4 describes our data and the procedure we use to identify<br />

transfer recipients. Secti<strong>on</strong> 5 discusses the characteristics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transfer recipients and<br />

Secti<strong>on</strong> 6 evaluates the balance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the exchange between the government and <strong>households</strong>.<br />

We evaluate the program’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> inequality and poverty in Secti<strong>on</strong> 7, and Secti<strong>on</strong> 9<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cludes.<br />

2 Why <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Subsidies for energy products and critical food items were first implemented during the<br />

Iran-Iraq war <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 1980s as a way to manage c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> during wartime. Over time,<br />

cheap energy and bread had become part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> life and Iranian c<strong>on</strong>sumers had built their<br />

lifestyles around them and producers made products with technologies that assumed energy<br />

would remain cheap forever. Attempts at <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing subsidies in small steps during the<br />

administrati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> presidents Rafsanjani and Khatami (1989-2001) were met with tough<br />

oppositi<strong>on</strong> from populist politicians and therefore did not succeed. Raising energy prices<br />

slowly did not work because each round <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> price increases intensified oppositi<strong>on</strong> to the<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and stopped further increases while inflati<strong>on</strong> wiped out the gains.<br />

In the meantime, Iran’s energy c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> was increasing at about 3 times as fast as its<br />

populati<strong>on</strong> and the country steadily became the most energy intensive country in the world:<br />

it used about 1.65 times as much energy per dollar <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> GDP as the United States, 2.42 times<br />

as much as Switzerland, and 2.5 times as much as nearby Turkey (Figure 1). Heavy demand<br />

led Iran to become an importer <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> gasoline during the late 2000s, which helped make the<br />

costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsidies explicit, and so paved the way for their eliminati<strong>on</strong>. Smuggling, which<br />

was comm<strong>on</strong> and widespread, became an embarrassing issue for the government. 4 Finally,<br />

the internati<strong>on</strong>al effort to stop Iran’s nuclear enrichment program was gathering strength<br />

and sancti<strong>on</strong>s that would prevent Iran from importing gasoline were looming (Guillaume,<br />

Zytek, and Farzin 2011).<br />

4 http://english.farsnews.com/newstext.php?nn=8810121174.<br />

4


Figure 1: Kilograms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oil (or equivalent) over $1000 GDP measured in 2005 PPP dollars,<br />

selected countries 1980-2010<br />

350<br />

Kilos <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oil equivalent per $1,000 GDP (2005 PPP)<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

Iran<br />

Turkey<br />

United States<br />

Switzerland<br />

0<br />

1980<br />

1981<br />

1982<br />

1983<br />

1984<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

2008<br />

2009<br />

2010<br />

Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators.<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al sancti<strong>on</strong>s against Iran, then looming in 2010 but not yet in full force,<br />

were another reas<strong>on</strong> why the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> gathered more widespread support. In particular, the<br />

threat <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sancti<strong>on</strong>s cutting Iran’s access to imported gasoline – by then accounting for about<br />

<strong>on</strong>e-third <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran’s c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> – added urgency to curbing the rising demand for gasoline.<br />

Although <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>ing Iran’s subsidies was urgent and l<strong>on</strong>g overdue, what prompted the<br />

populist president Ahmadinejad, not known for his trust in free markets, to push through the<br />

largest pro-market <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the country since Rafsanjani’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in the 1990s was most<br />

likely the regressive nature <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the energy subsidies. Ahmadinejad “rarely missed a chance<br />

to...[say] that 70 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the nati<strong>on</strong> [received] 30 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subsidies” (Harris 2010),<br />

and the regressivity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the energy subsidies was a central point in the massive government<br />

advertising campaign to sell the program.<br />

Figure 2 shows the extent to which subsidies accrued to individuals in different deciles<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> per capita income. Using the 2009 HEIS, we calculate household per capita expenditures<br />

(in 2009) <strong>on</strong> the main subsidized goods by deciles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> per capita income. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se expenditures<br />

are proporti<strong>on</strong>al to the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> (implicit) subsidies received, so the graph can also be<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidered to display the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subsidies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> bread <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> is the <strong>on</strong>ly <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

that is evenly distributed across income deciles, about PPP USD 5 per pers<strong>on</strong> per m<strong>on</strong>th.<br />

All others, especially gasoline, are skewed toward the rich. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> richest decile received about<br />

5


Figure 2: Expenditures per capita <strong>on</strong> subsidized goods per m<strong>on</strong>th and as a percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total<br />

expenditures, by income decile 1388<br />

35 <br />

4.0 <br />

30 <br />

3.5 <br />

2010 interna5<strong>on</strong>al dollars <br />

25 <br />

20 <br />

15 <br />

10 <br />

3.0 <br />

2.5 <br />

2.0 <br />

1.5 <br />

1.0 <br />

Percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total expenditures <br />

Gasoline <br />

Electricity <br />

Home heat <br />

Bread <br />

% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditures <br />

5 <br />

0.5 <br />

0 <br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 <br />

Deciles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> per capita income <br />

0.0 <br />

Notes: Home heating is primarily from natural gas and some kerosene.<br />

PPP USD 25 per m<strong>on</strong>th compared to less than 10 for the poorest decile. Table 7 provides<br />

figures to the same effect. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the total energy subsidies going to the richest decile<br />

was more than three times that received by the poorest decile, 19.2% compared to 6.0%.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> graph also shows that, in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> shares <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total expenditures, the poor relied more <strong>on</strong><br />

subsidies than the rich. Whereas subsidies comprised about 3.5 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the expenditures<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poorest decile, they were <strong>on</strong>ly 0.7 percent for the richest decile (the right axis).<br />

In the 2005 presidential electi<strong>on</strong>, candidate Ahmadinejad had campaigned, and many<br />

believe had w<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong> the promise to “put the nati<strong>on</strong>’s oil wealth <strong>on</strong> people’s dinner tables.”<br />

For six years this goal had eluded him. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omy was growing but in the eyes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> his<br />

supporters – and in actual fact – the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income was not improving, perhaps even<br />

getting worse, as the proliferati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> luxury cars in Tehran’s streets indicated. His earlier<br />

attempts at forcing an improvement in the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income, by redirecting the nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

investment funds, had not budged Iran’s high degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inequality (Salehi-Isfahani 2009),<br />

even after he had taken pers<strong>on</strong>al command <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Management and Plan Organizati<strong>on</strong>, the<br />

entity entrusted with allocating Iran’s public investment funds. In his sec<strong>on</strong>d term, and in<br />

the aftermath <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> his c<strong>on</strong>troversial re-electi<strong>on</strong> in 2009, the <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> presented itself as<br />

6


Table 1: Shares <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> for various items by income decile, 1388<br />

Income Bread Electricity Gasoline Home heat All Total<br />

decile<br />

energy<br />

1 9.09 6.22 3.74 7.20 6.02 6.85<br />

2 9.64 6.90 4.43 7.97 6.75 7.53<br />

3 9.79 8.06 5.18 8.64 7.55 8.16<br />

4 9.93 7.99 6.06 8.99 7.95 8.49<br />

5 10.01 8.74 7.20 9.18 8.53 8.93<br />

6 9.92 9.69 8.83 9.50 9.36 9.51<br />

7 9.97 10.16 10.99 10.21 10.41 10.29<br />

8 10.23 10.97 12.78 10.37 11.17 10.92<br />

9 10.23 12.98 15.00 11.91 13.01 12.26<br />

10 11.20 18.30 25.79 16.03 19.24 17.07<br />

Total 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00<br />

Source: HEIS and authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

the last opportunity for him to save his reputati<strong>on</strong> as a man <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the people. His desire to use<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> as a tool <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributi<strong>on</strong> prompted him to initially c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

cash transfers <strong>on</strong> family income and wealth, but as identificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>al incomes proved<br />

impractical, his pragmatist side w<strong>on</strong> and he decided to aband<strong>on</strong> the progressive scheme in<br />

favor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> uniform cash transfers (Harris 2010).<br />

Redistributi<strong>on</strong> may be the reas<strong>on</strong> why he waited nine m<strong>on</strong>ths to start the <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

program after it became law. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> TSR Act authorizing the government to remove the<br />

subsidies passed the parliament in January 2010, but the government started the program<br />

in late December, 2010. 5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government blamed the delay <strong>on</strong> lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> preparedness and<br />

administrative issues, but the late start suited president Ahmadinejad who could increase<br />

the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cash transfer without busting the annual limit set by the Act for redistributi<strong>on</strong><br />

to <strong>households</strong>. It is also well known that the President did not like the gradualist approach<br />

preferred by the law makers, which would increase prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> energy products and utilities<br />

close to their cost by the end <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Fifth Five Year Plan in 2015. He preferred to implement<br />

the full increase at <strong>on</strong>ce, and took advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fact that the TSR act had <strong>on</strong>ly set a<br />

ceiling for the total revenues raised from price increases. By waiting until the last quarter<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Iranian year 1389 (winter 2010-2011), the government was able to push through the<br />

entire price increase without exceeding this limit. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> delay permitted large price increases<br />

5 For a more detailed descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program and its implementati<strong>on</strong> see (Guillaume, Zytek, and Farzin<br />

2011).<br />

7


and cash transfers without breaking the letter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the law.<br />

With hindsight, maximizing the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the m<strong>on</strong>thly cash transfer was not shortsighted,<br />

it minimized the chances <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political backlash while increasing the threat to the program<br />

from inflati<strong>on</strong> later <strong>on</strong>. Larger cash transfers thus bought political support in the early<br />

phase at the expense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> support in the l<strong>on</strong>ger run. It has been widely reported, though<br />

the government has not <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficially acknowledged, that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> program has so far been<br />

in the red, meaning that the government paid out more to <strong>households</strong> than it collected in<br />

higher prices, by as much as 50%. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> deficit in the TSR program forced the government<br />

to borrow from the Central Bank, fueling inflati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

3 Implementati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cash transfer scheme<br />

What distinguishes Iran’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> program from those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> other countries, such as Nigeria,<br />

Bolivia, Pakistan, and Ind<strong>on</strong>esia prior to 2005, besides the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the price hikes, is the<br />

cash transfer scheme. Energy <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> throughout the developing world is typically<br />

unpopular and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten leads to violence. Experience shows that the most effective way to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>vince a majority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong>, especially the poor, that energy price <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s carry<br />

net benefits is to <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fer cash in return for higher prices. In Iran, this was d<strong>on</strong>e in two steps.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first step was to deposit the transfers in individual bank accounts, and letting the<br />

people know the m<strong>on</strong>ey was there but not allowing them to withdraw it. By seeing the<br />

actual m<strong>on</strong>ey in their bank accounts, participants gained c<strong>on</strong>fidence that the government<br />

would come keep its promise, unlike payments promised under the 2005 Justice Shares<br />

program that were rarely delivered (Harris 2012). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d step was to release the funds<br />

simultaneously with price increases. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first step helped build trust so that m<strong>on</strong>ths later<br />

when, <strong>on</strong> December 19, 2010, the president announced <strong>on</strong> nati<strong>on</strong>al televisi<strong>on</strong> that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

program would start at midnight, there was no rush to withdraw the funds the next day<br />

(Salehi-Isfahani 2011). Trust building may also explain why Iran’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> did not<br />

lead to street protests.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> TSR transfer <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about $45 per m<strong>on</strong>th per pers<strong>on</strong> (for up to six members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

household) was made available to any household head who completed a form and identified<br />

a bank account for into which the cash would be deposited. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> universal and uniform<br />

electr<strong>on</strong>ic deposits into individual bank accounts went a l<strong>on</strong>g way in reducing the type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

c<strong>on</strong>troversies that had plagued the Ind<strong>on</strong>esian cash transfer program where village leaders<br />

identified and registered the poor and sometimes collected the m<strong>on</strong>ey for them (Camer<strong>on</strong><br />

and Shah 2011). A side benefit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> using electr<strong>on</strong>ic bank transfers, in additi<strong>on</strong> to keeping<br />

8


corrupti<strong>on</strong> low, was that poor and rural people who had never used a bank before were<br />

motivated to learn to use the modern banking system. ATMs were set up in villages to enable<br />

rural families to withdraw their cash. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> applicati<strong>on</strong> could be completed electr<strong>on</strong>ically<br />

(though <strong>on</strong>ly 8.2% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> had internet access in 2010) or by hand. Although the<br />

government claims registrati<strong>on</strong> did not require supporting documents (Guillaume, Zytek,<br />

and Farzin 2011) anecdotal evidence suggests not <strong>on</strong>ly that it did, but also that not all<br />

registrants received funds. To attract applicants the government used a publicity campaign<br />

in print, radio, and televisi<strong>on</strong> to give instructi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> how to register for the program,<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> how the transfers were to be distributed, and the benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> (Atashbar<br />

2012). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re was also no penalty for late registrati<strong>on</strong>: a family registering two m<strong>on</strong>ths late<br />

would be eligible for the same amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total transfer as if it had registered at the beginning<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program. However, the government did request that wealthy families not register,<br />

and later <strong>on</strong> tried to drop these families from the transfer roll. But even with steps to<br />

ease access, especially for the poor, many w<strong>on</strong>dered whether illiterate heads <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household,<br />

families living in poor rural areas, and people who lacked access to the internet and media<br />

generally would register for the program.<br />

A few final steps helped ensure the program’s acceptance. A rati<strong>on</strong>ing program for<br />

gasoline had been in place for many years in which participants were issued smart cards<br />

that allowed them to purchase gasoline at a progressive rate based <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, and<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumers received a new allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> discounts just days before gasoline prices increased<br />

(Guillaume et al. 2011). Progressive pricing schemes also remained in place for homeheating<br />

fuels and electricity, easing the transiti<strong>on</strong> to higher prices. Finally, to c<strong>on</strong>trol<br />

inflati<strong>on</strong>ary expectati<strong>on</strong>s, the government instituted price c<strong>on</strong>trols, which were unevenly.<br />

From its incepti<strong>on</strong>, the program was widely and harshly criticized. By the beginning <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

2011 the government reported that 80% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong> had registered for the transfer<br />

program, but critics c<strong>on</strong>tended that this was a large overestimate. 6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re were also c<strong>on</strong>cerns<br />

that the underfunded program would be paid for by printing m<strong>on</strong>ey, adding m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

inflati<strong>on</strong> to the inevitable cost-push inflati<strong>on</strong> the program would cause. Despite these criticisms,<br />

in June 2012 the parliament extended the TSR to its sec<strong>on</strong>d phase, for a sec<strong>on</strong>d<br />

round <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> prices increases, but so far (December 2012) the government has not implemented<br />

the sec<strong>on</strong>d phase.<br />

In 2010 the government claimed that approximately 16 milli<strong>on</strong> bank accounts were<br />

opened to allow families to receive the transfer, that the banking sector improved their<br />

6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government reported that by May, 2011 over 90% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong> had registered for the TSR<br />

(Guillaume, Zytek, and Farzin 2011).<br />

9


ATM networks to handle the anticipated activity when the transfers became available, and<br />

that ATMs were expanded into rural areas to improve access. C<strong>on</strong>cerns remained, however,<br />

with an IMF report noting that “even the government’s more ardent opp<strong>on</strong>ents neither<br />

questi<strong>on</strong>ed the need for the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> nor its main elements, but argued that the government<br />

lacked the skills necessary to implement the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>” (Guillaume, Zytek, and Farzin 2011).<br />

4 Data and the identificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> recipients<br />

Our data come from the 1389 (2010/2011) round <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Household Expenditure and Income<br />

Survey (HEIS) collected by the Statistical Center <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran (SCI). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> HEIS is the principal<br />

annual household survey collected in Iran.<br />

It relies <strong>on</strong> a two-stage stratified sampling<br />

method and has been collected without pause for the past fifty years. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> total number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

observati<strong>on</strong>s is divided into roughly 12 equal sub-samples, each for <strong>on</strong>e m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the year<br />

(Table 2). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> HEIS c<strong>on</strong>tains detailed informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> household expenditures, ownership<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> amenities, and individual characteristics and incomes, but there is no explicit item for<br />

the cash transfer because the HEIS questi<strong>on</strong>naires had been printed and distributed before<br />

the TSR began. 7<br />

Fortunately, when the program did start, interviewers were instructed<br />

to record the transfer in the secti<strong>on</strong> “Miscellaneous Income,” under <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the six types<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income (tuiti<strong>on</strong> assistance, welfare payments, etc.). 8<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cash transfers were deposited<br />

every two m<strong>on</strong>ths, so we looked for items that equalled individual transfers (890,000=<br />

2x445,000 rials) times family size. Since this number rarely occurs by chance, it provided<br />

us with a method to identify transfer recipients. Approximately 98% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those reporting these<br />

numbers are household heads, c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the TSR’s procedure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> delivering transfers<br />

to family heads.<br />

While our identificati<strong>on</strong> procedure is not ideal it does a good job <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

counting the recipients in most provinces, as seen in Table 2. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> proporti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong><br />

reporting numbers equal to household size x 890,000 is very small before the TSR went<br />

into effect (less than 1%). Interestingly, <strong>on</strong>e-third <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> report receiving transfer<br />

before the program started but when transfers had been deposited into some participants’<br />

bank accounts. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se individuals likely c<strong>on</strong>fused having the m<strong>on</strong>ey in their bank accounts<br />

with having it to spend, indicating perhaps trust that the government was going to keep its<br />

word and release the m<strong>on</strong>ey. By Esfand (February 21-March 20), we find that 68.3% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

7 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> SCI was also the agency that c<strong>on</strong>ducted the ill-c<strong>on</strong>ceived wealth survey in 2009, so its <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficials knew<br />

the program was in the works, but presumably did not know when it would actually start.<br />

8 Within provinces the vast majority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> identificati<strong>on</strong>s were typically in <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e miscellaneous income<br />

sub-category: In Markazi, 100% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> identificati<strong>on</strong>s were in the scholarships category while in Ardebil 100%<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the identificati<strong>on</strong>s were in the home producti<strong>on</strong> category.<br />

10


Table 2: HEIS sample size and transfer recipients, 1389<br />

M<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> record Households Individuals Percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong><br />

in sample<br />

receiving transfer<br />

Urban Rural Total<br />

Farvardin 3101 12425 0.3% 0.2 0.3<br />

Ordibehesht 3332 13288 0.3 0.3 0.3<br />

Khordad 3217 12987 0.2 0.6 0.3<br />

Tir 3234 12984 0.2 0.8 0.3<br />

Mordad 3176 12678 0.2 0.1 0.2<br />

Shahrivar 3212 12725 0.1 0.1 0.1<br />

Mehr 3211 12740 0.3 0.6 0.4<br />

Aban 3172 12514 1.0 0.4 0.8<br />

Azar 3133 12368 32.4 40.3 34.6<br />

Dey 3189 12689 61.8 75.2 65.3<br />

Bahman 3146 12519 63.4 76.0 66.7<br />

Esfand 3109 12153 64.8 77.7 68.3<br />

1389-Q4 sample 9444 37361 63.3 76.3 66.8<br />

Notes: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> HEIS distributes its sample <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 38,232 <strong>households</strong> evenly across m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the year. Our<br />

working sample c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the observati<strong>on</strong>s for the last quarter.<br />

Source: HEIS and authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

families in the survey reported receiving transfers, which is below the 80% the government<br />

claimed at the time to be covering (Guillaume, Zytek, and Farzin 2011).<br />

One complicati<strong>on</strong> in our identificati<strong>on</strong> procedure is that the TSR leaves the definiti<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the family unit to applicants, while HEIS defines a household as the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people<br />

who live in physical unit and share expenditures. This caused some HEIS <strong>households</strong> to<br />

have more than <strong>on</strong>e TSR family. To account for this we c<strong>on</strong>sidered a household (defined<br />

by the HEIS) as being a transfer recipient if any its members reported any multiple <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

890,000 not exceeding 38 (2x19, which is the largest household size in the sample). In a few<br />

provinces, we found numbers that appeared to be cash transfers because they were multiples<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household size and a number close to 890,000. Adding these <strong>households</strong> to participants<br />

does not change the analysis significantly.<br />

Since we cannot determine with certainty how many people were registered in each<br />

household we cannot estimate the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual recipients, and so choose to express<br />

most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> our results in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong>. With the definiti<strong>on</strong> just given, we<br />

identify 34.6% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> as transfer recipients in the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Azar (before bank funds<br />

11


were released), 61.0% in Dey, 62.4% in Bahman, and 65.0% in Esfand. We should note that<br />

our identificati<strong>on</strong> method has a degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> uncertainty. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are false positives (people who<br />

did not receive any <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> but show a similar number in their miscellaneous incomes) and<br />

false negatives (those who did but added it to another miscellaneous income). 9 Given that<br />

our estimates fall well short <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the proporti<strong>on</strong> claimed by the government, especially in two<br />

provinces <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tehran and Hormozgan, we may have many more false negatives than false<br />

positives.<br />

Another complicati<strong>on</strong> is that for some <strong>households</strong> transfers were combined with actual<br />

miscellaneous incomes, where our method cannot detect them. To check, we subtracted<br />

the expected real amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transfer from each real miscellaneous income category from<br />

1387 to 1389 and recorded whether a household had any positive income remaining in that<br />

category. Comparing 1388-Q4 to 1389-Q4, we find a comparable percentage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong><br />

with positive incomes, except in Khuzestan and Khorasan Razavi, where in 1389 positive<br />

incomes were higher than usual, suggesting Type II error in these provinces. But even if<br />

all the <strong>households</strong> with positive incomes remaining in the expected transfer category after<br />

subtracti<strong>on</strong> were actually transfer recipients, our household identificati<strong>on</strong> would increase<br />

by <strong>on</strong>ly 3.4% for Esfand 1389, the m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the largest increase and the most important<br />

m<strong>on</strong>th to our later analyses. C<strong>on</strong>sidering these results together, we expect that our Type<br />

II error is moderate and the numbers we report based <strong>on</strong> the survey are <strong>on</strong>ly moderately<br />

underestimating the administrative data.<br />

Finally, variati<strong>on</strong> in the amount deposited or thought to have been deposited may account<br />

for under-identificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> recipients. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> transfer amount was changed several times<br />

in 1388 (2010) before <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficials settled <strong>on</strong> 890,000, so it is possible that amounts other than<br />

890,000 were deposited into recipients’ bank accounts or people reported not what was actually<br />

in the bank accounts but what they recollected from earlier news reports. Amounts<br />

equal to multiples <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household size and other numbers (810,000, 820,000 or 900,000 rials)<br />

were frequent enough to suspect that something like this happened. For instance, 22% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

<strong>households</strong> in Sistan reported a multiple <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 900,000 exactly equal to their household size<br />

in Esfand 1389, and 49.8% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> in Mazandaran reported a multiple <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 820,000<br />

9 In the m<strong>on</strong>ths before the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>ly 0.3% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> show up as “transfer recipients” using our<br />

criteria. Though we searched for any multiple <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 890,000 times 1 or 2 depending <strong>on</strong> the period, we do not<br />

expect household size as measured by the HEIS to differ much from household size as measured by the TSR.<br />

About 82.5% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> recipients got a m<strong>on</strong>thly transfer exactly 1 or 2 times their household size during the last<br />

quarter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1389. This figure rises to 95.3% when we let the multiple to vary between household size minus<br />

or plus <strong>on</strong>e, and to and 98.2% when minus or plus two. Our results are also c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the fact that<br />

provincial SCI <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fices were told to record the transfer in specific columns usually reserved for other items,<br />

such as scholarships and the like.<br />

12


exactly equal to household size, with n<strong>on</strong>e reporting these amounts before deposits began.<br />

We therefore expand our definiti<strong>on</strong> to include <strong>households</strong> that received <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these unusual<br />

amounts multiplied exactly by 1 or 2 times household size depending <strong>on</strong> the m<strong>on</strong>th. Our<br />

expanded definiti<strong>on</strong>, which we rely <strong>on</strong> as our primary definiti<strong>on</strong> for the remainder <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

paper, raises the percentage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> we identify as receiving cash transfer to 34.6%<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> in Azar, 65.3% in Dey, 66.7% in Bahman, and 68.3% in Esfand.<br />

5 Characteristics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> recipients and selecti<strong>on</strong><br />

In this secti<strong>on</strong> we c<strong>on</strong>sider whether the TSR achieved its equity goal: namely, whether its<br />

reach in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> geography and household characteristics was equitable. Given that in 1389<br />

about a third <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> families lived in rural areas, 25% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household heads were illiterate, and<br />

most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these families likely did not have a bank account, <strong>on</strong>e would expect that their initial<br />

participati<strong>on</strong> would be lower than average. But, as the survey results presented in Table<br />

3 reveal, rural <strong>households</strong> had greater participati<strong>on</strong> rates than urban <strong>households</strong> (76.3%<br />

compared to 63.3%). In terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family income, the TSR reached the middle income families<br />

most effectively, at rates around 70%. Both the poorest and the the richest deciles were<br />

the least likely to receive the transfer (59.6% and 55.0%, respectively). Participati<strong>on</strong> rose<br />

each m<strong>on</strong>th so that by Esfand, 1389, about 70.6% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong> (68.3% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong>)<br />

were receiving TSR payments. If we remove Tehran, which we suspect partially eluded our<br />

identificati<strong>on</strong> procedure, the lowest participating province, then the percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household<br />

receiving the transfer rises to 81.2% and the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people to approximately 82.6%,<br />

which are c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the rates announced by the government.<br />

A household’s geographic locati<strong>on</strong> was the most important determinant <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whether they<br />

received a transfer. Infrastructure development has lagged in areas such as Sistan and<br />

Baluchestan, Hormozgan, and North Khorasan, where the populati<strong>on</strong> tends to be poorer,<br />

more rural, and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> minority ethnic and religious backgrounds, and the TSR’s first few m<strong>on</strong>ths<br />

were yet another instance when these areas were left behind. In this respect the TSR seems<br />

to have had less success in overcoming these barriers. Figure 3 shows participati<strong>on</strong> rates by<br />

province for the last m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1389 (March-April 2011). Hormozgan had the sec<strong>on</strong>d lowest<br />

participati<strong>on</strong> rate (29.7%) after Tehran, whose 20.1% participati<strong>on</strong> rate is almost certainly<br />

due to lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> proper recording <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> miscellaneous incomes, and North Khorasan and Sistan<br />

and Baluchestan had participati<strong>on</strong> rates well below average (though the latter still received<br />

3.6% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the total transfer m<strong>on</strong>ey, commensurate with its populati<strong>on</strong> share). But there<br />

were other disadvantaged provinces that did quite well, such as Golestan, the sec<strong>on</strong>d least<br />

13


Table 3: Percent <strong>households</strong> receiving transfers by income decile, last quarter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1389<br />

Decile Rural Urban Total<br />

1 66.3 57.1 59.6<br />

2 76.5 67.7 70.1<br />

3 75.9 72.5 73.5<br />

4 77.1 69.6 71.8<br />

5 78.0 64.3 67.9<br />

6 76.7 69.5 71.5<br />

7 74.3 69.9 71.1<br />

8 77.2 65.7 68.6<br />

9 84.7 57.4 64.0<br />

10 74.8 48.3 55.0<br />

Total 76.3 63.3 66.8<br />

Source: Authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Note: Income deciles are calculated separately by m<strong>on</strong>th and rural-urban residence<br />

developed province <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran with a sizeable Turkmen populati<strong>on</strong>, where participati<strong>on</strong> reached<br />

91%. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> equally poor province <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ilam also did excepti<strong>on</strong>ally well, with a participati<strong>on</strong><br />

rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 93.9%. Variati<strong>on</strong> in the rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the provinces was relatively low: <strong>on</strong>ly five provinces<br />

fell below the overall average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 68.3% and twenty had over 80% participati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

While income, urban-rural residence, and province were three <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the most important<br />

determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong>, gender and educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the household head, and household<br />

size were also important. Female household heads received the transfer <strong>on</strong> average at a<br />

rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 8.2% less than male household heads, with a much larger rural disparity at 21.3%.<br />

Households with a college-educated head were the least likely to receive the transfer, at<br />

63.8%, while those with primary-educated heads were the most likely, at 70.5%. Illiteracy<br />

does not seem to have been a serious impediment, with 68.0% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> headed by an<br />

illiterate pers<strong>on</strong> receiving a transfer. Finally, larger <strong>households</strong> were more likely to receive<br />

the transfer. Only 42.3% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e-pers<strong>on</strong> <strong>households</strong> participated in the TSR, while 68.1%<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2-3 pers<strong>on</strong> <strong>households</strong>, 71.5% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 4-6 pers<strong>on</strong> <strong>households</strong>, and 75.3% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> with 7<br />

or more people participated. Clearly, the larger the total size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cash transfer the more<br />

likely that a household would participate.<br />

To understand the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these factors <strong>on</strong> participati<strong>on</strong> we estimated a<br />

semi-parametric probit regressi<strong>on</strong> in which the probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> receiving the transfer (participati<strong>on</strong>)<br />

is a functi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household characteristics and place <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residence.<br />

14


®<br />

Figure 3: Geography <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong>: percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong> receiving transfers by province<br />

Esfand 1389<br />

5<br />

Percentage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Households Receiving Transfer<br />

(90,100]<br />

(80,90]<br />

(50,80]<br />

[0,50]<br />

4<br />

6<br />

13<br />

17<br />

25<br />

20<br />

14<br />

16<br />

7<br />

2<br />

27<br />

1<br />

15<br />

18<br />

26<br />

24<br />

19<br />

3<br />

11<br />

8<br />

21<br />

28<br />

22<br />

23<br />

29<br />

9<br />

10<br />

30<br />

12<br />

1. Markazi<br />

2. Gilan<br />

3. Mazandaran<br />

4. E. Azarbaijan<br />

5. W. Azarbaijan<br />

6. Kermanshah<br />

7. Khuzestan<br />

8. Fars<br />

9. Kerman<br />

10. R. Khorasan<br />

11. Isfahan<br />

12. Sistan<br />

13. Kurdestan<br />

14. Hamadan<br />

15. Bakhtiari<br />

16. Lorestan<br />

17. Ilam<br />

18. Kohkiloyeh<br />

19. Bushehr<br />

20. Zanjan<br />

21. Semnan<br />

22. Yazd<br />

23. Hormozgan<br />

24. Tehran<br />

25. Ardebil<br />

26. Qom<br />

27. Qazvin<br />

28. Golestan<br />

29. N. Khorasan<br />

30. S. Khorasan<br />

Source: HEIS, US Geological Survey, and authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

15


transfer = α 0 + α 1 decile + α 2 urban + α 3 female + α 4 headedu<br />

+α 5 hhsize + α 6 married + α 7 prov+ɛ,<br />

where transfer indicates receipt <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a transfer, decile is the full set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> dummies for per capita<br />

income deciles, urban is a dummy indicating urban-rural residence, female indicates gender<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the household head, headedu is the educati<strong>on</strong> level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> head, hhsize is household size,<br />

married is marital status, prov are province dummies, and ɛ is the error term. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the household head was not significant so it is not included. Much <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> what we learn from<br />

estimating this equati<strong>on</strong> (see Table 4) c<strong>on</strong>firms our earlier observati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients in Table 4 represent the increase in probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> receiving the transfer<br />

with all independent variables at their means. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> table presents three sets <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> regressi<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

with the first including <strong>on</strong>ly income, urban, and gender; the sec<strong>on</strong>d adds educati<strong>on</strong> and marital<br />

status <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the the head, and the last regressi<strong>on</strong> includes dummy variables for provinces.<br />

In this discussi<strong>on</strong> we refer to the last column as we believe that accounting for province<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fers a more revealing picture <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong> by household characteristics. Including the<br />

full set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> province dummies increases the pseudo R 2 from 0.025 to 0.184. Households in<br />

middle income brackets (5-8 deciles) were more likely to participate than those in the poorest<br />

decile. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> middle class, which was c<strong>on</strong>sidered the likely loser <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>,<br />

at least participated more heavily than other income groups. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> bottom and top income<br />

deciles had the lowest unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al and c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al participati<strong>on</strong> rates. Urban families<br />

and those headed by women show lower participati<strong>on</strong> rates in the first column, in which<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly income is c<strong>on</strong>trolled for, in line with our earlier discussi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al pattern<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong>. When we c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> province <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residence, the gender effect disappears<br />

while the urban effect survives, showing 14.2% lower probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong>. In other<br />

words, gender <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the head did not matter as much within each province, but living in a<br />

rural area meant greater likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong> everywhere.<br />

Larger families participated at higher rates. Larger <strong>households</strong> typically have fewer<br />

earners per pers<strong>on</strong> and thus greater incentive to participate. Unmarried heads were less<br />

likely to participate, though this effect is not significant in the full probit. Educati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

mattered at the primary level; families headed by heads with <strong>on</strong>ly primary educati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

were 19.1% more likely to receive the transfer than illiterate household heads, and college<br />

educated heads were 22.0% more likely but the effect is not significant. Inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variables<br />

possibly c<strong>on</strong>nected with the ease <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> registrati<strong>on</strong>, such as possessi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a car or internet access,<br />

were not significant and did not significantly alter the probit results.<br />

16


Table 4: Probit regressi<strong>on</strong>s for the probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> receiving cash transfer, Esfand 1389<br />

(1) (2) (3)<br />

dF/dx z dF/dx z dF/dx z<br />

Income decile<br />

2 0.105 1.07 0.130 1.31 0.023 0.21<br />

3 0.231* 2.26 0.261* 2.52 0.179 1.59<br />

4 0.210* 2.03 0.248* 2.35 0.145 1.25<br />

5 0.322** 2.87 0.356** 3.12 0.282* 2.24<br />

6 0.270* 2.49 0.320** 2.86 0.282* 2.25<br />

7 0.326** 2.96 0.377** 3.3 0.222 1.78<br />

8 0.396** 3.46 0.469** 3.93 0.403** 3.08<br />

9 0.177 1.58 0.263* 2.21 0.255 1.92<br />

10 -0.039 -0.35 0.069 0.55 0.022 0.16<br />

Urban -0.172** -3.19 -0.194** -3.51 -0.142* -2.32<br />

Female -0.372** -4.86 -0.061 -0.52 -0.151 -1.18<br />

Household size 0.040* 2.37 0.062** 3.36<br />

Not married -0.265* -2.34 -0.206 -1.66<br />

Educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> head<br />

Primary 0.138* 2.09 0.191** 2.65<br />

Middle 0.059 0.70 0.064 0.69<br />

Sec<strong>on</strong>dary -0.080 -0.90 -0.003 -0.03<br />

College 0.120 1.06 0.220 1.75<br />

Province<br />

Fars 0.889** 3.44<br />

Ilam 0.927** 3.39<br />

Lorestan 1.055** 3.62<br />

Sistan -0.364* -1.99<br />

Tehran -1.379** -8.08<br />

C<strong>on</strong>stant 0.659** 9.29 0.416** 3.85 0.357* 2.08<br />

Pseudo R 2 0.019 0.025 0.184<br />

No. observati<strong>on</strong>s 3109 3089 3089<br />

Notes: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> final regressi<strong>on</strong> includes all provinces, but <strong>on</strong>ly selected provinces are displayed.<br />

p


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> importance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> province-level effects suggests that central administrative input affected<br />

participati<strong>on</strong>. 10 With the excepti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tehran and Hormozgan (with -137.9% and<br />

-126.5% lower participati<strong>on</strong> probabilities), where we suspect our identificati<strong>on</strong> strategy may<br />

be at fault, the variati<strong>on</strong> is probably due to the diligence with which the government promoted<br />

the program, the lead time between start and actual implementati<strong>on</strong>, and the development<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the banking infrastructure. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> lower likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> participati<strong>on</strong> in Sistan<br />

(-36.4%) is in line with its marginal status, both in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic development and cultural<br />

and religious affinity with Tehran. A similar explanati<strong>on</strong> is likely for North Khorasan<br />

(-47.9%).<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fer a mixed report card for the equitable reach <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cash transfer<br />

program. Whereas rural residents and those with low educati<strong>on</strong> fared well, residents <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

marginal provinces did not. We turn to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the transfer in the next two secti<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

starting with a general overview and then <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fering a detailed analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

<strong>on</strong> poverty and inequality.<br />

6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> TSR balance sheet for <strong>households</strong><br />

When the government enacted the TSR it struck a bargain with <strong>households</strong> to exchange<br />

higher energy prices for direct cash transfer. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re have been claims and counter claims<br />

from the government and its critics about whether <strong>households</strong> or the government w<strong>on</strong> in<br />

the bargain. Our survey data allows us to find some answers for the first three m<strong>on</strong>ths for<br />

the program. Since we do not know the added household expenditures as a result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> price<br />

increases, we compare the total expenditures <strong>on</strong> subsidized items with the cash transfers<br />

(Table 5).<br />

According to these estimates, during the first three m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR <strong>households</strong> spent<br />

approximately $3.25 billi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> energy products and water and received $7.77 billi<strong>on</strong> in cash<br />

transfers (all numbers c<strong>on</strong>verted at the then prevailing exchange rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 10,000 rials =<br />

$1). Deposits were made for two m<strong>on</strong>ths in Dey 1389 (December 2010) and <strong>on</strong>e m<strong>on</strong>th in<br />

Esfand 1389. This suggests that up to the end <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this period <strong>households</strong> were way ahead<br />

in the direct exchange with the government. 11 How did this balance hold for <strong>households</strong> in<br />

different income brackets? Table 6 shows the same data by deciles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income.<br />

Figure 4 shows that the total cash transfer received by families in different income<br />

10 We show the effects for selected provinces <strong>on</strong>ly. Markazi province near Tehran is the reference.<br />

11 We call this the direct exchange because even though we deflate the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cash transfers by the CPI<br />

for each m<strong>on</strong>th there are indirect general equilibrium effects that change the net gains by <strong>households</strong>).<br />

18


Table 5: Expenditures <strong>on</strong> subsidized items and transfers paid out in USD billi<strong>on</strong>s, 1389-Q4<br />

(2010-Q1)<br />

M<strong>on</strong>th Energy & water Cash Transfer Balance<br />

Dey 0.80 4.28 3.48<br />

Bahman 1.03 2.36 1.32<br />

Esfand 1.42 1.13 -0.29<br />

Q4 Total 3.25 7.77 4.52<br />

Note: Expenditures and cash transfers are based <strong>on</strong> informati<strong>on</strong> collected from the <strong>households</strong> in the survey.<br />

Source: Authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s from HEIS files<br />

Table 6: Expenditures <strong>on</strong> subsidized items and total transfers by decile in USD PPP billi<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

Q4, 1389<br />

Decile <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Expenditures <strong>on</strong> Cash<br />

Expenditures Energy Transfer<br />

1 0.61 6.41<br />

2 0.87 6.42<br />

3 0.91 7.26<br />

4 1.06 7.07<br />

5 1.08 6.77<br />

6 1.26 6.45<br />

7 1.38 6.71<br />

8 1.60 6.35<br />

9 1.77 5.18<br />

10 2.44 3.08<br />

Q4 Total 2.89 6.92<br />

Note: Expenditures and cash transfers are based <strong>on</strong> informati<strong>on</strong> collected from the <strong>households</strong> in the survey.<br />

Source: Authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s from HEIS files<br />

19


deciles (the bars) and as percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total income (the line). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transfers going<br />

to decile 1-7 was about three times <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the richest. Transfers also c<strong>on</strong>stituted a much larger<br />

percentage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the incomes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor: more than 28% for the lowest decile, falling to 2%<br />

for the richest.<br />

Figure 4: Total amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transfer received by income decile in billi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2010 PPP USD<br />

and transfer as a share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household income, Esfand 1389<br />

2.5 <br />

30 <br />

2010 PPP dollars <br />

2.0 <br />

1.5 <br />

1.0 <br />

0.5 <br />

25 <br />

20 <br />

15 <br />

10 <br />

5 <br />

Percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total income <br />

0.0 <br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 <br />

Source: HEIS and authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

0 <br />

While the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the transfer was far more progressive than energy subsidies,<br />

price increases still disproporti<strong>on</strong>ately affected the poor. As seen in Table 7, the TSR<br />

caused expenditures <strong>on</strong> subsidized items to grow by n<strong>on</strong>-trivial figures across all income<br />

deciles, particularly for the lower deciles. Whereas before the TSR the poorest three deciles<br />

used between 4.5% and 6.2% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their expenditures <strong>on</strong> subsidized goods (with the greatest<br />

expenditures <strong>on</strong> heating their homes), in Esfand, 1389, the third m<strong>on</strong>th after the TSR<br />

began, those figures grew to 7.8% and 11.2%. As seen in Table 7, while all deciles saw<br />

increases in their expenditures <strong>on</strong> affected items, the budget share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> affected items was<br />

largest for the poor and smallest for the rich.<br />

20


Table 7: Per capita m<strong>on</strong>thly expenditures <strong>on</strong> subsidized items by amount (rirals) and percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total expenditures, year<br />

1388 and Esfand 1389<br />

1388<br />

Home heat Water Electricity Utilities Bread Fuel Total<br />

1 24488 2.1 7600 0.6 9589 0.8 47498 3.9 22480 2.4 7253 0.4 69209 6.2<br />

2 26969 1.8 9282 0.6 10572 0.7 53127 3.5 23587 1.8 7659 0.4 76092 5.2<br />

3 29346 1.6 9659 0.5 12713 0.7 59365 3.1 23898 1.4 8951 0.4 82635 4.5<br />

4 29819 1.3 10476 0.5 12454 0.6 62152 2.7 24215 1.2 10828 0.4 85803 3.8<br />

5 30656 1.1 10800 0.4 13486 0.5 66240 2.3 24096 0.9 12737 0.3 89926 3.2<br />

6 31316 0.9 11469 0.3 14896 0.4 72361 2.0 23713 0.7 15883 0.3 95870 2.7<br />

7 33652 0.8 11926 0.3 15352 0.4 78815 1.7 24096 0.6 19533 0.3 102586 2.3<br />

8 33787 0.6 12435 0.2 16456 0.3 83267 1.4 24413 0.5 22203 0.3 107539 1.9<br />

9 39476 0.6 15275 0.2 19939 0.3 98370 1.4 24914 0.4 25989 0.3 122963 1.8<br />

10 54741 0.5 18314 0.2 28523 0.3 143844 1.2 28536 0.3 46112 0.3 171981 1.4<br />

Esfand 1389<br />

Home heat Water Electricity Utilities Bread Fuel Total<br />

1 59061 4.1 9267 0.8 13484 1.0 81222 5.8 53927 5.1 9605 0.4 142167 11.2<br />

2 87195 4.4 12166 0.7 18301 1.0 117052 6.0 55963 3.2 14678 0.6 186331 9.7<br />

3 78903 3.4 14379 0.6 19542 0.8 111697 4.7 55520 2.6 16750 0.5 181311 7.8<br />

4 97514 3.2 16559 0.6 22441 0.8 135232 4.6 58147 2.2 25440 0.6 216041 7.3<br />

5 104165 2.9 17165 0.5 27056 0.8 147725 4.2 64057 2.1 29219 0.6 239512 6.9<br />

6 136091 2.7 17008 0.4 25695 0.6 177815 3.7 57954 1.3 36103 0.6 267950 5.5<br />

7 112734 2.2 17035 0.4 26075 0.5 154105 3.0 57217 1.2 47417 0.7 257197 4.9<br />

8 143360 1.7 23618 0.3 28470 0.4 193794 2.4 61855 0.9 58627 0.6 308835 3.9<br />

9 129476 1.8 22272 0.4 35483 0.5 185611 2.6 66345 1.1 67662 0.5 312716 4.1<br />

10 217530 1.7 33852 0.3 54444 0.4 303450 2.4 65303 0.9 110342 0.6 472515 3.8<br />

Source: HEIS and authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

21


While these are by no means estimates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the welfare effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program, even for<br />

the early phase <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program, they do reveals that <strong>households</strong> received much more in<br />

cash transfers than they paid for their energy products in total during the fourth quarter<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1389 (winter 2011). Subsequently, as prices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> other products and earnings adjusted to<br />

higher energy prices, the balance in the exchange must have changed, perhaps against the<br />

<strong>households</strong> because wages and salaries do not appear to have kept up with inflati<strong>on</strong>, at<br />

least for the middle class. In 2011-12, as internati<strong>on</strong>al sancti<strong>on</strong>s against Iran intensified,<br />

real wages have most certainly declined, but we do not know how much <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the setbacks for<br />

<strong>households</strong> is due to <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>.<br />

7 Impact <strong>on</strong> poverty and inequality<br />

Energy subsidies are highly regressive, but the poor typically spend a much larger porti<strong>on</strong><br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their budgets <strong>on</strong> subsidized goods. This means that price increases following the removal<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsidies hit the poor the hardest. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> keys to the <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran’s <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> program <strong>on</strong><br />

poverty and inequality are in the cash transfer program and n<strong>on</strong>linear pricing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> gasoline and<br />

utilities, which partly protected the poor against the price hikes. In this secti<strong>on</strong> we c<strong>on</strong>sider<br />

the change in the poverty rate and in inequality during the first three m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR.<br />

We compare standard measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty and inequality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the actual distributi<strong>on</strong> with a<br />

simulated distributi<strong>on</strong> in which we subtract the cash transfers from household incomes.<br />

We begin with a look at the entire distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> incomes. Figure 5 displays the cumulative<br />

distributi<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>s for the actual and two simulated distributi<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> dashed line<br />

is the actual distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>households</strong>, the solid line is the no-transfer distributi<strong>on</strong> in which<br />

cash transfers are subtracted from incomes, and the dotted line is the simulated distributi<strong>on</strong><br />

labelled “universal coverage”, which adds transfers to incomes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those <strong>households</strong> that did<br />

not report receiving transfers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> no-transfers simulati<strong>on</strong> (simulati<strong>on</strong> 1) shows what would<br />

have happened had the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> not included any cash transfers, and the “universal coverage”<br />

simulati<strong>on</strong> (simulati<strong>on</strong> 2) represents complete and uniform targeting. Cash transfers clearly<br />

raised incomes across the board because the distributi<strong>on</strong> represented by the dashed line<br />

stochastically dominates the <strong>on</strong>e represented by the solid line. A similar view is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fered by<br />

the Generalized Lorenz curves depicted in Figure 6 for the three distributi<strong>on</strong>s. GL curves<br />

compare distributi<strong>on</strong>al informati<strong>on</strong> as well as the means <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these distributi<strong>on</strong>s. As these<br />

graphs show, cash transfers have unambiguously increased the welfare for all income groups<br />

during the first three m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR.<br />

Table 8 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fers specific measures for poverty and inequality based <strong>on</strong> these distributi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

22


Figure 5: CDFs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> log per capita income for observed data and two recipient simulati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

with US $3 day and regi<strong>on</strong>al poverty lines, Esfand 1389<br />

Probability


<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> top two panels, labeled “Observed”, present our estimated poverty rates using the last<br />

m<strong>on</strong>th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the surveys for 1388 (2009) and 1389 (2010). We use regi<strong>on</strong>al poverty lines calculated<br />

by Salehi-Isfahani and Hashemi (2007) for the rural and urban areas <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 30 provinces<br />

based <strong>on</strong> the methodology developed by Chen, Datt, and Ravalli<strong>on</strong> (1993). This methodology<br />

usually is applied to distributi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenditures, but since cash transfers are registered<br />

as incomes not expenditures, we interpret the expenditure poverty lines in Salehi-Isfahani<br />

and Hashemi (2007) as income thresholds that we use to define who is poor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty<br />

lines in 1389 rials are 14,909 per pers<strong>on</strong> per day in rural areas and 23,702 in urban areas<br />

(about PPP $3 and $4.5). Observed poverty is lower in Esfand, 1389, compared to the same<br />

m<strong>on</strong>th the year before (9.7% vs. 11.1%). This decline may be due to cash transfers but it<br />

is possible that other factors were at work. A rigorous <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> analysis is not possible given<br />

the nature <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> our data, but to get an idea <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the magnitude <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cash transfers relative to<br />

the incomes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor we compare the observed poverty rates in 1389 with those from the<br />

simulated distributi<strong>on</strong> that subtracts transfers from each household’s income (simulati<strong>on</strong><br />

1). Doing so, increases the poverty rate from 12.0% to 20.2% in rural areas and from 8.8%<br />

to 12.0% in urban areas. In this definiti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> “<str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g>”, transfers can be said to have lifted,<br />

albeit temporarily, 8% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rural populati<strong>on</strong>, or 1.8 milli<strong>on</strong> people, and 3.2% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the urban<br />

populati<strong>on</strong>, or 1.7 milli<strong>on</strong> people, out <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poverty. Nati<strong>on</strong>ally this amounts to a reducti<strong>on</strong> in<br />

the poverty rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 4.7%, or 3.5 milli<strong>on</strong> fewer poor people.<br />

Turning to measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inequality, also in Table 8, we note that the Gini coefficient<br />

hardly changes when we remove transfers from the incomes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all <strong>households</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Gini<br />

for the observed data is 0.39 compared to 0.41 for the no-transfer simulati<strong>on</strong>. This could<br />

be that initially higher income groups participated in the TSR at lower rates. But since<br />

cash transfers were more important for incomes at lower deciles, the Gini, which is equally<br />

sensitive to changes in upper and lower parts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the distributi<strong>on</strong>, is not the appropriate index.<br />

For this reas<strong>on</strong> we also employ General Entropy indices which allow placing the emphasis<br />

<strong>on</strong> different parts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the distributi<strong>on</strong>. Interestingly, GE(-1), which is more sensitive to<br />

redistributi<strong>on</strong> at the lower end <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the income distributi<strong>on</strong>, shows the inequality difference<br />

due to cash transfers to be much higher, 0.38 for the actual distributi<strong>on</strong> versus 0.47 for the<br />

<strong>on</strong>e without transfers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> GE indices with higher parameter values behave more like the<br />

Gini index.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this secti<strong>on</strong> challenge the widely held beliefs that pro-market <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s,<br />

especially those that reduce subsidies, are rarely in the interests <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the poor. This has also<br />

been <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the principal reas<strong>on</strong>s for oppositi<strong>on</strong> to <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Iran. What we notice<br />

from examining <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> during the initial phase <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR is that it reduced both poverty<br />

24


Table 8: Inequality and percent in poverty for urban and rural areas, actual and simulated,<br />

Esfand 1388-89<br />

Poverty GE(-1) GE(0) GE(1) GE(2) Gini<br />

percent<br />

Observed, Esfand 1388<br />

Rural 13.4 0.35 0.25 0.24 0.32 0.37<br />

Urban 10.3 0.40 0.25 0.23 0.27 0.37<br />

Total 11.1 0.46 0.28 0.26 0.32 0.40<br />

Observed, Esfand 1389<br />

Rural 12.0 0.32 0.24 0.25 0.33 0.38<br />

Urban 8.8 0.33 0.24 0.24 0.32 0.37<br />

Total 9.7 0.38 0.27 0.27 0.36 0.39<br />

Simulati<strong>on</strong> 1: No transfer, Esfand 1389<br />

Rural 20.2 0.45 0.29 0.29 0.39 0.41<br />

Urban 12.0 0.37 0.26 0.26 0.34 0.39<br />

Total 14.4 0.47 0.30 0.29 0.39 0.41<br />

Simulati<strong>on</strong>s 2: Universal coverage, Esfand 1389<br />

Rural 10.5 0.27 0.22 0.23 0.32 0.37<br />

Urban 7.2 0.29 0.23 0.23 0.31 0.37<br />

Total 8.2 0.33 0.26 0.26 0.35 0.39<br />

Impact: Simulati<strong>on</strong> 1 minus simulati<strong>on</strong> 2, Esfand 1389<br />

Rural 8.2 0.12 0.05 0.04 0.06 0.03<br />

Urban 3.2 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.01<br />

Total 4.7 0.09 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.02<br />

Notes: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> no-transfer case subtracts transfers from recipients’ incomes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> universalcoverage<br />

case adds transfers to incomes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all <strong>households</strong>.<br />

Source: Authors’ calculati<strong>on</strong>s, HEIS 2010.<br />

and inequality. This may be the single most important reas<strong>on</strong> why <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Iran<br />

did not meet the kind <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oppositi<strong>on</strong> and revolt that similar <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s in developing countries<br />

have faced.<br />

25


8 Bey<strong>on</strong>d the early phase<br />

In September 2013, the TSR has been in operati<strong>on</strong> for two and a half years. In this period,<br />

both energy prices and cash transfers have remained c<strong>on</strong>stant while prices have doubled.<br />

While the household sector was by and large (over)compensated, energy price hikes have<br />

dealt a serious shock to producti<strong>on</strong>. In some sectors, such as transportati<strong>on</strong>, price increases<br />

were rolled back (diesel prices increases were kept to 9 times instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 22 times), but<br />

general lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> flexibility in the movement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> productive factors, both capital and labor,<br />

combined with price c<strong>on</strong>trols, slowed the adjustment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> firms to the new envir<strong>on</strong>ment. A<br />

year after the TSR went into effect, tightening <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> internati<strong>on</strong>al sancti<strong>on</strong>s against Iran dealt<br />

an even more serious blow to the ec<strong>on</strong>omy. Iran’s oil exports, which account for 80% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

the country’s foreign exchange earnings, dropped by half precipitating a currency crisis,<br />

devaluati<strong>on</strong> and more inflati<strong>on</strong> (Salehi-Isfahani 2012). Lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> clear evidence regarding<br />

the <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR <strong>on</strong> the ensuing macroec<strong>on</strong>omic instability has led many observers<br />

and policy makers in Iran to be highly sceptical <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the wisdom <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the initial program and,<br />

more importantly, <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>tinuing with energy price adjustments. A serious impediment in<br />

identificati<strong>on</strong> is the inability to pinpoint the source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the huge rise in liquidity in the last<br />

two years. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government has purposefully restricted the disseminati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> macroec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

data citing the emergency c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s surrounding Iran’s nuclear dispute with the West.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> TSR was not fully funded and estimates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its deficit range from $15-25 billi<strong>on</strong>, but<br />

other unfunded government programs, such as the Maskan Mehr noted earlier, are likely<br />

bigger c<strong>on</strong>tributors to rising liquidity and inflati<strong>on</strong>. But citing, its inflati<strong>on</strong>ary potential,<br />

the TSR’s opp<strong>on</strong>ents have so far successfully blocked the implementati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its “Phase 2”,<br />

which promised to energy raise prices again and raising the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sash transfers. Given<br />

the presumed deficit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the first phase, and the high inflati<strong>on</strong> in the last few m<strong>on</strong>ths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2012,<br />

the proposal to increase cash transfers <strong>on</strong>e more time could not garner sufficient support in<br />

Iran’s parliament.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> record <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> price increases since the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR indicates the importance<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these other factors. Figure 7 plots the (annualized) m<strong>on</strong>thly inflati<strong>on</strong> rates for the last<br />

two years. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> vertical line to the left marks the <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> in December 2011 and the<br />

<strong>on</strong>e to the right marks the tightening <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sancti<strong>on</strong>s a year later. Not surprisingly, inflati<strong>on</strong><br />

appears to increase immediately after subsidies were removed, to about 50% annually, but<br />

declined to less than 20% three m<strong>on</strong>ths later. This is c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the fact that energy<br />

price increases were a <strong>on</strong>e-time event and the dampening effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> price c<strong>on</strong>trols. Inflati<strong>on</strong><br />

picked up with renewed vigor several m<strong>on</strong>ths later with the first bout <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> devaluati<strong>on</strong>, and<br />

26


Figure 7: M<strong>on</strong>thly rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inflati<strong>on</strong> following <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

then again after September 2012 which saw the collapse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rial.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR <strong>on</strong> household welfare bey<strong>on</strong>d its first three m<strong>on</strong>ths is in c<strong>on</strong>siderable<br />

doubt. General price increases have no doubt been followed by increases in most<br />

wages and salaries. Government salaries have not kept up with inflati<strong>on</strong>, hurting a large<br />

secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the middle class for whom the rebates have been less significant. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

decline engendered by the sancti<strong>on</strong>s and the unstable macroec<strong>on</strong>omy may have wiped out<br />

much <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the gains by lower income families from the cash transfers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> oppositi<strong>on</strong> to the<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> mounted such that the program was essentially suspended. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> new government<br />

which took <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fice in August 2013 has promised to revive the program, but fear <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inflati<strong>on</strong><br />

may cause further delay. In the meantime, energy prices are falling in real terms and the<br />

old c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> habits are returning.<br />

9 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong><br />

By the late 2000s Iran had the largest energy subsidies in the world. While the deficit was<br />

menti<strong>on</strong>ed, the government was more c<strong>on</strong>cerned with waste, smuggling, and inefficiency.<br />

Equity was sec<strong>on</strong>d order but close behind, with wealthy Iranians disproporti<strong>on</strong>ately enjoying<br />

energy subsidies. A major problem for implementing <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> was political acceptance, an<br />

anxiety made serious by the failures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the liberal Khatami and Rafsanjani governments to<br />

secure <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> populist, Ahmadinejad, was able to straighten the kinks that c<strong>on</strong>stricted<br />

previous presidents and met his equity goals by making large cash transfers available to all<br />

Iranians, a compensati<strong>on</strong> for the large and immediate price increases, the successful other<br />

27


half to the steep price rises <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Targeted Subsidy Reform program (TSR).<br />

Fuel subsidies are comm<strong>on</strong> in the developing world but <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> is not. When countries<br />

such as Bolivia, Nigeria, and Pakistan attempted large price increases they did not also<br />

compensate their citizens with cash payments; each had to aband<strong>on</strong> its <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. In Iran,<br />

as in Ind<strong>on</strong>esia, payments helped cushi<strong>on</strong> the shock to poorer families. While it is still too<br />

early to draw firm less<strong>on</strong>s from Iran’s experiment with <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and in some ways<br />

it is particular to the situati<strong>on</strong> in Iran, there are a few aspects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran’s program that may<br />

have wider relevance. For <strong>on</strong>e thing, Iran’s program was less motivated by the need for<br />

budgetary c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s because much <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> was foreg<strong>on</strong>e earnings in the form<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the country’s own oil and gas distributed at low cost. This allowed the government to<br />

sell the <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> package as <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> program replacing another, replacing the regressive<br />

fuel subsidies with uniform cash transfers, rather than as a scheme to save m<strong>on</strong>ey for the<br />

government. In the event it <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fered a generous exchange to <strong>households</strong> and lost m<strong>on</strong>ey in<br />

the bargain. In additi<strong>on</strong>, Iran’s program was seen as the attempt by a populist president<br />

with a l<strong>on</strong>g standing promise to distribute oil revenues more equally. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se two elements<br />

went a l<strong>on</strong>g way in preventing an immediate negative reacti<strong>on</strong> from lower-income urban<br />

people. We show that in fact, at least during its first three m<strong>on</strong>ths, the program did deliver<br />

<strong>on</strong> its promises <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributi<strong>on</strong> to ordinary Iranians: there were significant improvements<br />

in poverty and inequality as a result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR transfers.<br />

Other parts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the program that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fer less<strong>on</strong>s for future programs are related to TSR’s<br />

innovative implementati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government devised a mechanism to make the transfer<br />

easy to obtain, implementing an easy registrati<strong>on</strong> process, expanding the banking sector to<br />

increase coverage in rural and other disadvantaged areas, depositing transfers directly into<br />

bank accounts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> applicants, and undertaking a public relati<strong>on</strong>s campaign. In particular, we<br />

believe that letting depositors see the cash transfers in their bank accounts before prices were<br />

jacked up went a l<strong>on</strong>g way to establish trust between the government and the populati<strong>on</strong><br />

regarding the impending exchange.<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the TSR is not limited to its immediate aims <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> reducing waste and<br />

distorti<strong>on</strong>s and redistributing income to the poor. In a country that has received about<br />

half a trilli<strong>on</strong> dollars <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oil revenues over the last decade, this was the very first time that<br />

ordinary people have received a direct transfer representing their rights as citizen in sharing<br />

in that wealth. Iran’s oil wealth has been shared with the country’s poor before, but always<br />

in indirect ways as expenditures <strong>on</strong> infrastructure, health and educati<strong>on</strong>, or as oil m<strong>on</strong>ey has<br />

trickled down the ec<strong>on</strong>omic ladder. While direct transfers may be less effective in generating<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, cash transfers are more effective from a political ec<strong>on</strong>omy perspective.<br />

28


References<br />

Atashbar, T. (2012). Illusi<strong>on</strong> therapy: How to impose an ec<strong>on</strong>omic shock without social<br />

pain. Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Policy Modeling 34, 99–111.<br />

Bac<strong>on</strong>, R. and M. Kojima (2006). Coping with higher oil prices. Technical report, World<br />

Bank.<br />

Beat<strong>on</strong>, C. and L. L<strong>on</strong>toh (2010, October). Less<strong>on</strong>s learned from Ind<strong>on</strong>esia’s attempts to<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> fossil-fuel subsidies. Technical report, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Institute for Sustainable<br />

Development.<br />

Camer<strong>on</strong>, L. A. and M. Shah (2011). Mistargetting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cash transfers, social capital destructi<strong>on</strong><br />

and crime in Ind<strong>on</strong>esia. Technical report, Department <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic, University<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Melbourne, available at http://users.m<strong>on</strong>ash.edu.au/~clisa/papers/BLT_<br />

JPubE.pdf.<br />

Chen, S., G. Datt, and M. Ravalli<strong>on</strong> (1993). Is poverty increasing in the developing world?<br />

Policy research working paper 1146, World Bank: Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC.<br />

Guillaume, D., R. Zytek, and M. R. Farzin (2011). Iran – the chr<strong>on</strong>icles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>.<br />

IMF working paper 98, E2.<br />

Harris, K. (2010). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Politics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Subsidy Reform in Iran. Middle East Report 40.<br />

Harris, K. (2012). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rise <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Subc<strong>on</strong>tractor State: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Politics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pseudo-<br />

Privatizati<strong>on</strong> in the Islamic Republic <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Iran. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Middle Eastern<br />

Studies (forthcoming).<br />

Hassanzadeh, E. (2012). Recent developments in irans energy <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>s. Technical<br />

report, Global Susbisides Initiative, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Insittute for Sustainable Development.<br />

IMF (2013). Energy <str<strong>on</strong>g>subsidy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g>: less<strong>on</strong>s and implicati<strong>on</strong>s. Report, Internati<strong>on</strong>al M<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

Fund.<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al Energy Agency (2010). World energy outlook. Technical report, Internati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

Energy Agency.<br />

Nili, M. (2010). Arzyabi piamadhaye eslahe nezam yaraneh enerzhi (An evluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the refrom <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> energy subsidies). Tehran, Iran: Pegahan Andisheh.<br />

Salehi-Isfahani, D. (2009). Poverty, inequality, and populist politics in Iran. Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Inequality 15 (1), 5–24.<br />

Salehi-Isfahani, D. (2011). Iran: Subsidy <str<strong>on</strong>g>reform</str<strong>on</strong>g> amid regi<strong>on</strong>al turmoil. Brookings Institusi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC, http://www.brookings.edu/research/opini<strong>on</strong>s/2011/03/<br />

03-iran-salehi-isfahani.<br />

Salehi-Isfahani, D. (2012). Friends like these: How the sancti<strong>on</strong>s might hurt America’s<br />

potential allies inside Iran. Foreign Policy, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, DC, http://www.<br />

foreignpolicy.com/articles/2012/10/12/with_friends_like_these.<br />

29


Salehi-Isfahani, D. and A. Hashemi (2007). Regi<strong>on</strong>al poverty in Iran. Technical report,<br />

Virginia Tech.<br />

30

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!