14.01.2014 Views

The Broken Window Revisited - Hubertlerch.com - HubertLerch.com

The Broken Window Revisited - Hubertlerch.com - HubertLerch.com

The Broken Window Revisited - Hubertlerch.com - HubertLerch.com

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Broken</strong> <strong>Window</strong> <strong>Revisited</strong><br />

by Hubert Lerch<br />

Introduction<br />

Frédéric Bastiat (1801-1850) was born into the France of Napoleon I. Napoleon Bonaparte, a<br />

soldier by profession, began his political career with a coup d'état in 1799. In 1804 he made<br />

himself Emperor of the French. <strong>The</strong> Battle of Waterloo in 1815 marked the fall of his Empire.<br />

Napoleon reorganized France, exported the French mercantile model to Europe, and thought of<br />

merging the European states into one. A child of the French Revolution, he believed in a state<br />

that resembled a military encampment with a chain of <strong>com</strong>mand, provisioning, pomp and glory.<br />

Neither did Napoleon care about casualties, nor did he waste any thought on how such display<br />

of power would be paid for. For all these reasons we can say that the history of the modern<br />

state begins with Napoleon I. All modifications<br />

– the militaristic states of Germany, Italy, Russia,<br />

Japan, and the U.S. today – are mere copies and perfections of the original model.<br />

With Napoleon in <strong>com</strong>mand, Bastiat experienced statism writ large first hand. Never before had<br />

France been more centralized, more planned, more militarized, in short more “ state ” in the<br />

modern sense. That which is seen, and that which is not seen, published in 1850, is Bastiat's<br />

answer to Napoleon's despise of freedom and the free market. Two years before the book was<br />

published, Napoleon's nephew, known in history as Napoleon III, had already been elected<br />

president of the National Assembly. A year later he should carry out his own coup d'état<br />

followed by the proclamation of the Second Empire, to the day 48 years after his uncle's<br />

coronation. Napoleon III became famous for the reconstruction of Paris, a typical mercantile<br />

project, and a number of military adventures, among them the Crimean War of which AJP Tayler<br />

said “ the war that did not boil ” although it helped to stabilize the regime domestically.<br />

Intercaled between these two Napoleonic Empires we find the Restoration, divided into the<br />

Bourbon phase with Louis XVIII and Charles X, both brothers of Louis XVI who was murdered<br />

during the Revolution, and the Orléans phase from 1830 to 1848. <strong>The</strong> political ups and downs<br />

during this period of French history stand in stark contrast to its economic continuity. What a<br />

great subject to study for a man who was not taken in by appearances, nor by bombastic words<br />

or gestures!


<strong>The</strong> <strong>Broken</strong> <strong>Window</strong> is Chapter I of Bastiat's book. And Henry Hazlitt, who should make it<br />

famous, opens his Economics in One Lesson with the <strong>Broken</strong> <strong>Window</strong>s fallacy. He identifies<br />

"the broken-window fallacy, under a hundred disguises," as "the most persistent in the history of<br />

economics" (Hazlitt, p. 25) and consequently dedicates his whole book to issues like:<br />

• the confusion between demand and need (especially evident in the alleged blessings of<br />

war)<br />

• the illusion that printing money makes a nation richer<br />

• the myth of supply-driven prosperity<br />

This essay does not argue the economic side of <strong>The</strong> <strong>Broken</strong> <strong>Window</strong>. Instead, it applies<br />

Bastiat's model to politics, more precisely to the problem of order. For this purpose we first state<br />

the problem using Bastiat's simple model, replacing the boy by a Security Competitor and the<br />

glassmaker by a Windfall Producer. <strong>The</strong>n we modify this basic model little by little to gain<br />

deeper insights into the very nature of the modern state. First, we replace the Security<br />

Competitor by a Security Monopolist and the Windfall Producer by a Security Provider. <strong>The</strong>n we<br />

introduce, one at a time, a Perception Manager, a Money Manager, and finally a Dream Factory.<br />

<strong>The</strong> parameters used in this essay are the following:<br />

Model 1:<br />

• SC = Security Competitor<br />

• WP = Windfall Producer<br />

• P = Producer<br />

Model 2:<br />

• SM = Security Monopolist<br />

• SP = Security Provider<br />

Model 3:<br />

• PM = Perception Manager<br />

Model 4:<br />

• MM = Money Manager<br />

Model 5:<br />

• DF = Dream Factory


Model 1: <strong>The</strong> Question of Order<br />

In <strong>The</strong> <strong>Broken</strong> <strong>Window</strong> a boy smashes a shopkeeper's window. We do not know anything of the<br />

boy's motivation, whether it happened on purpose or by accident. Eventually we learn that the<br />

shopkeeper has his window repaired and that he pays the glassmaker the due price for his new<br />

window. <strong>The</strong> villagers discuss the incident and conclude that the boy was not an evildoer but a<br />

benefactor. After all, didn't the glassmaker receive money from the shopkeeper?<br />

Bastiat insists that what we see is only half of the story. While it is true that the glassmaker's<br />

trade was stimulated by the incident, the shopkeeper pays for something that he already had<br />

rather than spending his savings on things he wished to possess. On the surface we only see a<br />

normal business transaction: the shopkeeper gives money to the glassmaker in return for a<br />

good, the new glass. <strong>The</strong> villagers, at first upset by the disturbance of public order, soon forget<br />

that the shopkeeper loses twice, first the old window and second the money earmarked for<br />

consumption or investment. But the shopkeeper is not the only one who loses. Equally<br />

important is the fact that not only other producers but also everyone else in the whole<br />

<strong>com</strong>munity lose because the multiplier effect of the shopkeeper's planned expenditure fails to<br />

materialize.<br />

<strong>The</strong> problem posed in the <strong>Broken</strong> <strong>Window</strong> is however not only an economical one.<br />

Psychological, political and moral questions are also addressed. For further investigation we<br />

divide the local <strong>com</strong>munity (society) into two groups: the majority of the passive spectators but<br />

formal decision-makers (the voters) and the minority of the actors, on and behind the stage,<br />

whose game is about power and wealth. If we assume that the players want to continue to play<br />

the game, we can neglect the passive majority because they are only needed inasmuch as they<br />

allow the players to play the game again. <strong>The</strong> following graphical models focus almost entirely<br />

on the actors and ignore the passive mass formally represented as producer P.<br />

Model 1: Natural Order challenged


We now can distinguish between two kinds of order: the original order before the boy smashed<br />

the window pane and the new order in which the boy appeared in a favorable light. <strong>The</strong> first<br />

reaction of the villagers clearly shows that they saw the boy's action as an act of destruction,<br />

morally unacceptable, socially disruptive, economically destructive, and therefore a challenge to<br />

order.<br />

In Bastiat's model we <strong>com</strong>pletely miss any hint to the state: there is no mayor, no policeman, no<br />

public prosecutor, no judge. Why do the villagers eventually accept the challenge to order in the<br />

absence of coercion? What prevented them from sympathizing with the shopkeeper and<br />

punishing the boy? As interesting as these questions may be, we should not be sidetracked by<br />

them. Irrespective of their response to the challenge, at one point they will restore the old order,<br />

even after an interlude of chaos. <strong>The</strong> reason for a return to such a natural equilibrium, or natural<br />

order, is man's constitution or nature. <strong>The</strong> old order is grounded on a threedimensional<br />

coordinate system with the vectors justice, property, and contract. Despite the promise so many<br />

utopias make to <strong>com</strong>pletely eradicate this coordinate system and supplant it by a new one, in<br />

practice all these experiments in social engineering have failed, as they were flawed in theory.<br />

Model 2: <strong>The</strong> Monopolization of Security<br />

Model 1 discussed the challenges to the old order and the restoration of a natural equilibrium in<br />

the absence of coercion. In the next step we create an environment where a natural equilibrium<br />

cannot be reached due to systemic violent intervention.<br />

Model 1 tacitly assumed that the boy acted spontaneously, irrationally and irresponsibly. Model<br />

2 replaces the singular agent by an agency, <strong>com</strong>monly known by the name of state. Both boy<br />

and state use violent means to ac<strong>com</strong>plish their goals but the agency called state (from the<br />

Latin “stare” meaning “ to stay ”) differs from the agent in respect to duration which results from<br />

a higher degree of organization.<br />

With the Security Competitor (SC) replaced by a Security Monopolist (SM), we have another<br />

new player, the Security Provider (SP). <strong>The</strong> boy lacked any concept and the glassmaker only<br />

harvested the windfalls of the boy's inconsiderate action. Now we are dealing with two<br />

professional players in the game. Both specialize in the production of security and both depend<br />

on each other. It is obvious that their cooperation benefits both monopolists to the detriment of


everyone else. That both co-prosper can be derived from the following assumptions:<br />

• <strong>The</strong> Security Provider<br />

• finances election campaigns<br />

• offers posts to ex-politicians (for example, as consultants or members on the board<br />

of directors)<br />

• creates jobs in strategic quantities (in numbers just big enough to be<br />

propagandistically exploitable)<br />

• serves as national identifier<br />

• delays marginalization<br />

• finds in the Security Monopolist a big and dependable buyer for un<strong>com</strong>petitive<br />

products<br />

• helps to legitimize institutionalized robbery (taxation) in the name of security<br />

• <strong>The</strong> Security Monopolist<br />

• grants subventions and protectionism<br />

• has a specialized and dependent supplier<br />

• has a scapegoat to blame for self-inflicted problems<br />

• domesticates capitalism and makes it "socially acceptable"<br />

• gains the image of a <strong>com</strong>petent crisis manager<br />

• enjoys stability through moderate, controlled change<br />

At this point it is important so see that with organization <strong>com</strong>es <strong>com</strong>plexity. Not only interaction<br />

between the two monopolists, or interaction between the active and the passive elements of<br />

society change in quality, the individual agencies also be<strong>com</strong>e bigger, more differentiated, more<br />

difficult to control. In short, the agencies be<strong>com</strong>e subject to differentiation of which<br />

bureaucratization can be used as reliable indicator. While their original purpose remains<br />

unchanged – to realize and protect their monopoly on violence – their sheer growth in<br />

<strong>com</strong>bination with their errors weaken their legitimacy.<br />

Bureaucratization is the price to pay for higher <strong>com</strong>plexity. But organization also requires more<br />

rationality, specialization, and, in general, <strong>com</strong>petence. Athenian democracy managed more or<br />

less to keep bureaucratization minimal but only at the expense of <strong>com</strong>petence. If every citizen<br />

can fill any public position, the quality of the decisions made must by necessity be low. Modern<br />

mass democracy, being less egalitarian, tolerates an increasing number of public functions to<br />

grow beyond democratic control. What some criticize as undemocratic, others defend as more


efficient (so Colin Crouch in Post-Democracy). In any case, the democratically legitimized<br />

political sector is more and more burdened with the task to legitimize all the sectors where<br />

democratic influence is minimal. With the growing imbalance between Security Provider and<br />

Security Monopolist in favor of the first, whose trump card is better organization, the Security<br />

Monopolist slowly mutates into a Security Legitimizer. We do, however, not follow up on this<br />

development here.<br />

Model 2: Natural Order replaced by Artificial Order<br />

Model 3: <strong>The</strong> Production of Majorities<br />

Model 2 discussed the institutionalization and monopolization of security. Omitted were the<br />

influences cooperation between Security Monopolist and Security Provider have on society. <strong>The</strong><br />

production of security is expensive. We find many examples in history of how it ruined even<br />

large and rich societies. We also know from history that the production of security is influenced<br />

by a number of factors like geography (conflict only occurs where cooperation is possible),<br />

technology (weapons of mass destruction do not only need mass societies but also mass<br />

technology that makes destruction easy and cheap), constitution and others more. Here we are<br />

only interested in constitution or, in modern language, political system. <strong>The</strong> reason for this is<br />

simple: we want to find out how power is legitimized. And depending on the political system,<br />

power is legitimized in different ways. In a democracy, power is legitimized by “ the people ”,<br />

more precisely by a majority of “ the demos” (those given the right to vote). A closer look<br />

confirms two things:<br />

• legitimization in large, <strong>com</strong>plex societies always means umbrella legitimization<br />

Almost all activities of state organs<br />

–<br />

police, judiciary, military, education, welfare, to<br />

mention only the central ones – are not directly subjected to the will of the voters. And yet<br />

they all claim to act “ in the name of the majority ”.<br />

In the previous section we attributed


this phenomenon to a higher degree of organization.<br />

• legitimization is, and can only be, formalized and ritualized<br />

Without formal framework legitimization fails. Occasions must be created, occasions like<br />

elections on all levels. Often times it suffices to merely dissipate doubt. However,<br />

legitimization, in order to be seen as such, must continuously be formally or informally<br />

reenacted. Election campaigns have be<strong>com</strong>e void of content and highly ritualized. On<br />

election day the average voter finds himself confronted with the problem to choose<br />

between images and image carriers (faces) rather than ideas and programs. That he acts<br />

irresponsibly – defined as incapable of making a reasonable decision – cannot surprise<br />

the observer. David Friedman in Hidden Order has pointed out that any investment of<br />

scarce resources – time and energy – is disproportionate to the expected gain. Seen from<br />

the viewpoint of legitimization, it does not matter what the voter actually does, he has<br />

only three options:<br />

• to choose between several faces (valid ballot)<br />

• to reject all faces (abstention)<br />

• to select more than one face (invalid ballot)<br />

Since any of the voter's three possible actions legitimizes the Security Monopolist in the<br />

same way, the voter inevitably fades out of the picture.<br />

In a liberal democracy<br />

–<br />

and all our positive associations with democracy stem from this early<br />

phase of its mutation<br />

–<br />

we see a society held together by strong historical, cultural, religious,<br />

and similar bonds where the production of majorities is relatively easy. <strong>The</strong> history of our party<br />

landscape confirms this picture. At the beginning we find two parties, the monarchists and the<br />

constitutionalists (groupings who, for purely selfish reasons, preferred to entangle Leviathan in a<br />

system of obligations or checks and balances) while the electorate was limited to men of age<br />

and property. Majorities were more difficult to <strong>com</strong>e by when societies industrialized. <strong>The</strong><br />

socialist division into two parties, although with roots in their theory, must also be understood as<br />

a desperate attempt at reducing growing <strong>com</strong>plexity.<br />

Little is left of the liberal ideal but the liberty to equality in the voting process (so Christoph<br />

Möller in Demokratie<br />

–<br />

Zumutungen und Versprechen. 2008). In a society of powerless,<br />

illiterate, and poor individuals majorities can only be gained through technology because, as


Jacques Ellul had argued convincingly half a century earlier, the illusion of modern man consists<br />

in the fact that all do the same while they strongly feel that they act freely and independently.<br />

Modern mass tourism could serve as a good illustration for Ellul's point.<br />

Model 3: In Quest of Majorities<br />

In a utopian democratic state where the will of the individual is exactly identical with the will of<br />

all, the problem of legitimization does not even arise. In a society where the political sphere is<br />

not legitimized by “ the people ”, a conflict of interest between the ruler and the ruled can be<br />

observed despite the fact that rulers justify their existence by referring to a greater, usually<br />

divine, order of which they themselves are merely pieces. On the other hand, the deeper the<br />

divide between ruler and the ruled in a democratic constitution, the more legitimacy be<strong>com</strong>es an<br />

issue. We can study in history that democratization went hand in hand with mediation. During all<br />

most radically democratic phases of modern history – for instance the Reign of Terror during the<br />

French Revolution, the revolution of 1848, the Paris Commune of 1870, the two Russian<br />

revolutions of 1917<br />

– we observe a steep increase in the use of “ enlightenment ” or, in more<br />

profane words, propaganda. This is not an accident. What we now call, in more scientific<br />

verbiage, perception management, be<strong>com</strong>es a necessity in a system that only acknowledges<br />

“ the people ” as the root of its legitimacy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> scheme designed by Security Provider and Security Monopolist for their mutual advantage<br />

would not be saleable to the masses without mass education, mass propaganda dished out by<br />

institutions ranging from public schools to the mass media. <strong>The</strong> images the masses perceive<br />

are produced or mediated, they are not natural or self-evident. <strong>The</strong> Perception Manager's main<br />

function is to describe the world in a way that broadly corresponds with both Security Provider's<br />

and Security Monopolist's interests. It would fail, however, if the Perception Manager <strong>com</strong>pletely<br />

dropped the claim to somehow represent reality. An image is not simply a lie, it is a purposeful<br />

distortion of reality. As a consequence, an image cannot be proven wrong. It can only be shown<br />

inaccurate, insufficient, or oversimplistic. However, lack of <strong>com</strong>plexity is a weak argument


against a strategy of immunization, what image production really is. It immunizes against<br />

criticism, discredits the critic, and eventually reinforces a specific perception. Another<br />

prerequisite for an image to be acceptable is chaos or confusion. Images kick in only if the world<br />

is seen as <strong>com</strong>plex, even chaotic, opinions as contradictory and confusing. <strong>The</strong> more<br />

in<strong>com</strong>prehensible the world, the more people cry out for plausible explanations that bring<br />

meaning and order into their world. That is exactly what images are meant to ac<strong>com</strong>plish.<br />

Model 4: <strong>The</strong> Production of Fictitious Wealth<br />

Model 3 discussed the crucial role of the Perception Manager for the legitimacy of a democratic<br />

political system. Model 4 explains the need to underpin perception with substance. As we know<br />

from studies in mass psychology, words and the images they convey sway the masses. Charts<br />

and numbers support and objectivize images and create expectations. With them <strong>com</strong>es the<br />

optimistic belief in amelioration, today primarily expected from technical solutions (the word<br />

“ solution ” itself is a purely technical term, like so many others in our political jargon).<br />

However, even the best and most subtle propaganda will eventually fail if the masses see it<br />

disconfirmed by their collective experience. Hitler without full employment is just a big mouth.<br />

Few asked how full employment was achieved. But full employment as a fact was a powerful<br />

argument in his favor. And yet he only applied Keynsian economics, like so many others after<br />

him until the present day. That Hitler blindly trusted a banker, Hjalmar Schacht, when it came to<br />

financial jugglery also set a precedent. But Hitler took special care to play off the various<br />

interests against each other, even within his own party, so successfully that party, state, and<br />

nation in the end would only function as long as he was at the helm. As soon as he was no<br />

more, all political organs quickly disintegrated.<br />

Today's cartel of power, military industrial <strong>com</strong>plex, money, and opinion is not organized around<br />

a dictator, not even a single party. Even where the state is traditionally strong, i.e. in countries<br />

with a de facto single party structure, the four players act in concert. Democracy's lauded<br />

multistability results from the smooth functioning of this cartel more than from the daily operation<br />

of its non-legitimized bureaucracy because of the vested interests that brought it into existence<br />

in the first place.


Model 4: <strong>The</strong> Cartel of Power, Military Industrial Complex, Money, Opinion<br />

Over the past twenty years, however, one of the four players moved to the fore: the Money<br />

Manager. In order to understand why the tail came to wag the dog we must briefly look into the<br />

nature of democracy. As stated above, of all poliical systems democracy enjoys by far the<br />

weakest legitimization since it depends on “ the people ”, its whims, its moods, its appetites, its<br />

dreams. All democracies in history sooner or later find themselves entangled in promises that<br />

they cannot keep: the promise of happiness, the promise of a carefree life, the promise of old<br />

age, the promise of education for all, the promise of technological progress, the promise of<br />

peace, and many other promises. Some of these promises are purely utopian, others are simply<br />

counterproductive, and still others are plainly idiotic. But they are made nonetheless and a huge<br />

machinery is set in motion to realize them. That is costly and can only be justified by pointing to<br />

an allegedly higher public good. With liberalism shed like a dead skin, “Gemeinnutz geht vor<br />

Eigennutz ” (the <strong>com</strong>mon good before the private good) was made state doctrine in all<br />

democratically legitimized countries, not only in Nazi Germany.<br />

A politician who wants to be reelected must have a record of his “ achievements ” – a highway<br />

here, an airport there, a park, a public library, etc. etc. And the good news is that all these<br />

“ achievements ” don't cost money. <strong>The</strong> best politicians even insist that economic criteria do not<br />

apply to politics. And by pumping hot air into the bubbles that politicians are selling to their<br />

voters, the Money Manager turbocharged the machine.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Money Manager, of course, pursues his own objectives whose main is to acquire the<br />

biggest junk of the cake. As long as his activities contribute to the production of wealth there is<br />

no problem. A problem arises when real resources are being replaced by promises. This, in<br />

simple terms, is the phenomenon of the hot money bubble. Although originally a political<br />

problem, it is not only highly addictive but also devastating because it affects the real economy.<br />

Even though it cannot keep its promise to produce wealth out of thin air, it keeps its promise to<br />

shift wealth from one group to another. What once was the dream of kings to have an alchimist


produce gold has be<strong>com</strong>e the reality of our age. <strong>The</strong> charlatans of a distant past have fallen into<br />

oblivion but our age has its own wizzards, heroes, shakers. And with quasi religious attitude<br />

appropriate for a secular age we expect salvation from men of god-like stature and devilish<br />

intention.<br />

Hot money bubbles alone, however, tend to burst dragging down what is left of the real<br />

economy (in some economies, e.g. Britain, the real economy has dropped to a mere 10 percent<br />

of the entire economy!). Multiple economic crises ensue, with more tax money laundered, i.e.<br />

moved from many pockets to a few secret accounts. With the global economy the size of the<br />

impact changes: whole continents are brought into the orbit of the Money Manager. <strong>The</strong><br />

European Union and its currency, both never popular among Europeans, would never have<br />

seen the light without him. How much mighty states have shackled themselves to powerful<br />

financial interests is a daily tragedy in all advanced democratic countries. While the Money<br />

Manager produces bubbles rather than wealth he satisfies his state-affiliated clientele rather<br />

than the general consumer. More and more sections of the regular economy he forces to<br />

dysfunction. This process is cynically described in Ayn Rand's Atlas Shrugged Book 1.<br />

In the next stage the Security Monopolist expands so drastically and produces such a big mob<br />

of unemployed or semi-unemployed that the state officials plus the mob in <strong>com</strong>bination generate<br />

enough political leverage to support the regime. Socialization intensifies, regular producers<br />

be<strong>com</strong>e more dispensable and are openly denigrated as "predatory capitalists", they are driven<br />

into insolvency or low-tax countries, the consumers fall back into some sort of traditionalist<br />

economy, be<strong>com</strong>e do-it-yourself men and self-suppliers or start operating in the gray zone. <strong>The</strong><br />

Perception Manager paints primitive but digestible black-and-white images, simple enough for<br />

the mob to be swallowed. <strong>The</strong> mob sets the standards: sex, gossip, alcohol and sports satisfy<br />

the physical, intellectual, and psychic standards of the masses.<br />

Model 5: <strong>The</strong> Production of La La Land<br />

Model 4 discussed the significance of the Money Manager in a system that promises milk and<br />

honey and his role in the production of fictitious wealth. Although the system appears to be<br />

multistable, it stomps out negative feedback and be<strong>com</strong>es a closed system without capability of<br />

self-correction. A single trigger, which in itself may be ridiculous, can now destabilize the system<br />

and bring it to the point of collapse which, needless to emphasize, would not only destroy the


system itself but also the world as we know it. That, without a doubt, makes mandatory the<br />

construction of la la land, a land of happy slaves living in bubbles of hot air.<br />

La la land is a deliberate effort, not inevitable. Its intellectual roots are relativism, Freudianism,<br />

and a fervent belief in technical progress, <strong>com</strong>bined with democracy, the utopian dream of<br />

meaningful involvement. As modern man is hopelessly drowning in a sea of information and<br />

disinformation but unable to <strong>com</strong>municate meaningfully, he is starved of propaganda which<br />

alone allows him to find orientation. Reduction of <strong>com</strong>plexity is what he is desperate for, and<br />

what he inevitably gets. La la land is the land of the Last Men where “ everyone wants the same;<br />

everyone is the same: he who feels differently goes voluntarily into the madhouse ” (Friedrich<br />

Nietzsche: Zarathustra).<br />

While in Models 1 through 4 the producer/consumer stands outside of the game, Model 5<br />

reintegrates him. Like in the hyperdemocratic totalitarian states of the 20 th<br />

century, the<br />

individual merges into the collective, only that political contents have evaporated. No more is it<br />

about antagonistic ideologies, no longer about an apocalyptic struggle between the forces of<br />

good and evil<br />

–<br />

they were anachronistically invoked for the last time to mobilize the mass<br />

emotion against the abstract idea of terrorism. Totalitarianism has gained a new quality: instead<br />

of control of the masses from outside, the masses now control themselves within the framework<br />

spontaneously defined by “ the circumstances ”. <strong>The</strong> state ceases to act, it merely reacts. To<br />

borrow from the military, we could call the new phenomenon total democracy. It is totalitarian in<br />

its grip, democratic in its appearance, contradictory in its self-understanding, empty in its theory,<br />

inescapable in its pretention, suffocating in its omnipresence.<br />

Model 5: <strong>The</strong> Sweet Lethal Fragrance of La La Land


Conclusion<br />

Beginning with Bastiat's <strong>Broken</strong> <strong>Window</strong> we asked the question of order. We stated that in the<br />

absence of a monopolistic enforcer or Security Monopolist society would always return to the<br />

equilibrium of a natural order. In the second model we changed one parameter in such a way<br />

that the natural order could no longer be established. To change one parameter, however,<br />

impacts another. With growing specialization the political system quickly loses legitimacy which<br />

invites a third change. Words alone, as important as they are in politics, won't bridge the<br />

widening gap between ruler and the ruled. In a scientific age, everything is quantifiable and<br />

people want to hear numbers. He who plays with numbers wins the battle, but he who produces<br />

them wins the war. Before it is noticed, the state finds itself trapped. Too much in love with an<br />

advantageous can-do-image, an allure of greatness, a promise to buy the world, the democratic<br />

state is <strong>com</strong>pelled to destroy its very foundation, the people. Now a mere abstract entity, the<br />

real people find themselves bullied and ripped off. <strong>The</strong> democratic state morphs into a<br />

dictatorship where the end<br />

– democracy as a utopian abstractum – justifies all means. Now,<br />

everything is turned on its head: Injustice is Justice, Slavery is Freedom, Poverty is Wealth,<br />

Indoctrination is Education. Orwellian Newspeak has be<strong>com</strong>e the language we speak in a game<br />

that leaves most of us speechless.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!