30.01.2014 Views

Macroeconomic strategies, agriculture and rural poverty in post ...

Macroeconomic strategies, agriculture and rural poverty in post ...

Macroeconomic strategies, agriculture and rural poverty in post ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Macroeconomic</strong> <strong>strategies</strong>, <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>post</strong>-apartheid South Africa<br />

Charles Mather <strong>and</strong> Asghar Adelzadeh<br />

Introduction<br />

So serious are these problems [<strong>poverty</strong>, <strong>in</strong>equality] that macroeconomic policies that<br />

exacerbate either risk underm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the fragile social fabric so carefully nurtured <strong>in</strong> the<br />

mid-1990s. Any stabilisation policy that was based on a worsen<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>in</strong>come distribution would<br />

be a highly risky one (St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g, Sender <strong>and</strong> Weeks 1996, 19).<br />

In June 1996 South Africa’s M<strong>in</strong>ister of F<strong>in</strong>ance released his <strong>post</strong>-apartheid<br />

macroeconomic bluepr<strong>in</strong>t. The Growth, Employment <strong>and</strong> Redistribution plan (Gear)<br />

appeared to mark the end of a period of <strong>in</strong>tense debate over the economic strategy which<br />

would most effectively reshape the country’s economic l<strong>and</strong>scape <strong>and</strong> address the crucial<br />

issues of <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality (Hart 1994; Nattrass 1994; Kapl<strong>in</strong>sky 1994; Sender 1994;<br />

Adelzadeh 1996a). In the period lead<strong>in</strong>g up to the 1994 democratic elections, there were two<br />

lead<strong>in</strong>g contenders for the country’s economic policy: on the one h<strong>and</strong> African National<br />

Congress (ANC) th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g appeared to be congruent with a strategy developed by the<br />

<strong>Macroeconomic</strong> Research Group (Merg), an organisation that had close l<strong>in</strong>ks with the ANC<br />

itself <strong>and</strong> the labour movement through the Congress of South African Trade Unions<br />

(Cosatu). Merg called for a programme of fiscal expansion directed towards social <strong>and</strong><br />

physical <strong>in</strong>frastructure, a ‘balanced’ monetary policy, <strong>and</strong> a more active role for the state <strong>in</strong><br />

the economy (Merg 1993). The apartheid government’s economic position, on the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, was represented by the Normative Economic Model, a report which emphasised the<br />

need for fiscal discipl<strong>in</strong>e, strict monetary control, <strong>and</strong> a free market environment. These two<br />

extremes <strong>in</strong> macroeconomic th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g - described variously as heterodox vs orthodox<br />

(St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g et al 1996), growth strategy school vs fiscal discipl<strong>in</strong>e school (Gibson <strong>and</strong> van<br />

Seventer 1996), <strong>and</strong> supply-side vs dem<strong>and</strong>-side policies (Nattrass 1994; 1996) - provided the<br />

broad frame of reference for debate <strong>in</strong> the period lead<strong>in</strong>g up to <strong>and</strong> after the 1994 elections.<br />

The high po<strong>in</strong>t of debate over macroeconomic policy <strong>in</strong> the period after the elections<br />

was 1996, a year which was “...rich <strong>in</strong> contrast<strong>in</strong>g economic visions <strong>and</strong> growth <strong>strategies</strong>”<br />

(Nattrass 1996, 25). In the first half of 1996 representatives of both bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong> labour preempted<br />

the government by releas<strong>in</strong>g their own macroeconomic proposals. The South<br />

African Foundation, a group of the largest <strong>and</strong> most powerful bus<strong>in</strong>ess organisations <strong>in</strong><br />

South Africa, released its ‘Growth for All’ strategy <strong>in</strong> February 1996. Predictably the strategy<br />

called for decreased government expenditure, policies to encourage private <strong>in</strong>vestment, the<br />

further deregulation <strong>and</strong> privatisation of the economy, a flexible labour market, a vigorous<br />

export drive, <strong>and</strong> removal of all exchange controls (Rix 1996; F<strong>in</strong>ancial Mail 8 March 1996).<br />

Representatives of the labour movement delivered their response - ‘Social Equity <strong>and</strong> Job<br />

Creation’ - a few months later. While big bus<strong>in</strong>ess called for fiscal restra<strong>in</strong>t, labour’s six<br />

pillars of growth proposal was <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with an expansionary fiscal policy aimed at job creation<br />

<strong>and</strong> worker tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, the improvement of <strong>in</strong>frastructure, an active l<strong>and</strong> reform programme,<br />

<strong>and</strong> a strategy to <strong>in</strong>crease domestic dem<strong>and</strong> for locally manufactured goods (Adelzadeh<br />

1996b). When Gear was released <strong>in</strong> June 1996, it drew very different responses from the<br />

ma<strong>in</strong> policy players. While the details of the macroeconomic policy were ‘music to the ears of<br />

Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Day 14 March 1997), Gear has played a significant role <strong>in</strong> stra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

relations between the ANC <strong>and</strong> Cosatu (Eidelberg 1997). Indeed, the secretary general of


Cosatu, Sam Shilowa, responded to the macroeconomic strategy by stat<strong>in</strong>g that it would have<br />

been ‘<strong>in</strong>conceivable’ to the ANC <strong>in</strong> the period before the 1994 elections. 1<br />

With a restrictive fiscal policy <strong>and</strong> a commitment to free market pr<strong>in</strong>ciples, Gear is not<br />

very different from a st<strong>and</strong>ard IMF/World Bank structural adjustment programme. Indeed,<br />

this is a policy which owes much to the ‘Wash<strong>in</strong>gton consensus’ (Taylor 1997). The<br />

similarities between Gear <strong>and</strong> the neo-liberal model are <strong>in</strong> fact strik<strong>in</strong>g: compare, for<br />

<strong>in</strong>stance, Broham’s (1996 108) description of the neo-liberal model, which <strong>in</strong>volves the<br />

“..adoption of an open, market-led economic regime of export oriented <strong>in</strong>dustrialization<br />

based on trade liberalization, direct foreign <strong>in</strong>vestment, <strong>and</strong> the export of goods for the<br />

world market”, with Gear’s emphasis on the importance of a “competitive outward oriented<br />

economy” <strong>and</strong> a programme of “accelerated tariff liberalisation” to guarantee “a stable<br />

environment for confidence <strong>and</strong> a profitable surge <strong>in</strong> private <strong>in</strong>vestment” (Republic of South<br />

Africa 1996, 1-5). Despite its considerable deviation from earlier ANC economic th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

the government’s decision <strong>in</strong> favour of a conservative macroeconomic policy emphasiz<strong>in</strong>g<br />

fiscal austerity <strong>and</strong> tight monetary control was not entirely surpris<strong>in</strong>g. Nor did it represent, as<br />

the bus<strong>in</strong>ess press has suggested, a new phase <strong>in</strong> ANC economic policy (e.g. Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Day 14<br />

March 1997). As early as 1992 there were <strong>in</strong>dications that ANC economic th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g was<br />

shift<strong>in</strong>g away from the proposals drawn up by Merg <strong>and</strong> towards a strategy dom<strong>in</strong>ated by<br />

fiscal restra<strong>in</strong>t <strong>and</strong> strict monetary control (Nattrass 1994). The release of the 1994 White<br />

Paper on the Reconstruction <strong>and</strong> Development Programme confirmed the direction of<br />

change <strong>in</strong> ANC economic th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g: the paper marked a radical reversal <strong>in</strong> economic th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>and</strong> a “...very significant compromise to the neo-liberal, ‘trickle down’ policy preferences of<br />

the old regime” (Adelzadeh <strong>and</strong> Padayachee 1994, 1).<br />

While Gear is a product of a new phase <strong>in</strong> ANC economic th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g that may be traced<br />

back to the early 1990s, various economic events <strong>in</strong> the mid-1990s ensured that the shift to a<br />

more conservative economic policy was not reversed. In 1995 the economy was faced with a<br />

balance of payments crisis that was perceived as a threat to the macroeconomic stability of<br />

the economy. And <strong>in</strong> the first few months of 1996 the value of the R<strong>and</strong> lost more than<br />

30% of its value <strong>in</strong> relation to the other major currencies. These were clearly not ultimately<br />

responsible for Gear’s emphasis on fiscal austerity <strong>and</strong> neo-liberalism; nevertheless these<br />

cont<strong>in</strong>gencies did shore up any l<strong>in</strong>ger<strong>in</strong>g support with<strong>in</strong> the ANC leadership for a strategy<br />

based on fiscal expansion as proposed by Merg <strong>and</strong> the labour movement.<br />

These debates <strong>and</strong> decisions on economic policy have come at a time when the depth<br />

<strong>and</strong> extent of <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> South Africa is be<strong>in</strong>g exposed through an important<br />

countrywide survey on liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ards. The results of the 1993 Project for Statistics on<br />

Liv<strong>in</strong>g St<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> Development (PSLSD) which surveyed 9,000 households has<br />

confirmed what numerous regional <strong>and</strong> local studies <strong>in</strong>dicated: that South Africa rema<strong>in</strong>s one<br />

of the most unequal societies <strong>in</strong> the world, that there is a strong race dimension to <strong>poverty</strong>,<br />

that there are more poor people <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas, <strong>and</strong> that women <strong>and</strong> children are affected<br />

more seriously by malnutrition, destitution <strong>and</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> (RDP 1995; May 1996; May, Carter<br />

<strong>and</strong> Posel 1995). Of all the PSLSD results the most strik<strong>in</strong>g is the depth of <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong>: the<br />

data <strong>in</strong>dicate that three quarters of the population liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas live below the <strong>poverty</strong><br />

1<br />

1 Cosatu has gone so far as to suggest that it might contest the 1999 elections separately from the ANC<br />

(F<strong>in</strong>ancial Mail, 17 January 1997).


l<strong>in</strong>e. 2 The nature of <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> South Africa raises several important questions on the<br />

relationship between <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> Gear. Indeed, the macroeconomic strategy must ultimately<br />

be judged on its ability to redistribute wealth more equally <strong>and</strong>, <strong>in</strong> the South African context,<br />

improve the livelihoods of the <strong>rural</strong> poor. Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the impact of Gear on <strong>agriculture</strong>, an<br />

important source of livelihood for poor <strong>rural</strong> people, <strong>and</strong> Gear’s emphasis with<strong>in</strong> the l<strong>and</strong><br />

reform programme, is one way of beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g to explore the relationship between <strong>rural</strong><br />

<strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> South Africa’s new macroeconomic strategy.<br />

This report moves beyond the abstract debates on the appropriateness of different<br />

macroeconomic <strong>strategies</strong> for South Africa <strong>and</strong> explores the possible impacts of Gear on<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>rural</strong> livelihoods. It beg<strong>in</strong>s by exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the position of <strong>agriculture</strong> with<strong>in</strong> the<br />

South African economy us<strong>in</strong>g published <strong>and</strong> unpublished <strong>in</strong>formation. It exam<strong>in</strong>es why<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> was s<strong>in</strong>gled out for its potential contribution to growth <strong>and</strong> job creation by policy<br />

analysts from very different ideological positions. The second section of the paper exam<strong>in</strong>es<br />

Gear’s strategy for the economy <strong>and</strong> contrasts its approach to <strong>agriculture</strong> with previous<br />

policy positions. The last two parts of the paper explore the probable impact of an open<br />

export-oriented economy on commercial <strong>agriculture</strong>, <strong>rural</strong> livelihoods, <strong>and</strong> on small scale<br />

farmers, a key component of l<strong>and</strong> reform <strong>in</strong> South Africa.<br />

Agriculture <strong>in</strong> South Africa’s Economy<br />

There have been several attempts to specify <strong>and</strong> quantify the contribution of <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

to South Africa’s broader economy (Faux 1990; L<strong>in</strong>desay 1991; van Rooyen, Fenyes, <strong>and</strong> van<br />

Zyl 1987; van Zyl, van der Vyver <strong>and</strong> Groenewald 1988; van Zyl <strong>and</strong> V<strong>in</strong>k 1988). Most<br />

concur that the sector’s direct contribution to gross domestic product (GDP), employment<br />

<strong>and</strong> exports has decl<strong>in</strong>ed significantly <strong>in</strong> the <strong>post</strong>-war period. Agriculture’s share of GDP has<br />

dropped from a high of over 17% <strong>in</strong> the 1950s to around 4% <strong>in</strong> the 1990s (Abstract of<br />

Agricultural Statistics 1995). While data on the number of people employed on commercial<br />

farms is notoriously <strong>in</strong>accurate, the broad pattern reflects a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the number of farm<br />

workers <strong>in</strong> the <strong>post</strong> war period, but especially s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1970s. The number of people<br />

employed <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> has decl<strong>in</strong>ed from a high of more than a million <strong>and</strong> a half <strong>in</strong> the<br />

1970s to less than 1 million <strong>in</strong> the 1990s. When considered <strong>in</strong> relation to the work<strong>in</strong>g<br />

population as a whole, these decl<strong>in</strong>es are even more dramatic: <strong>in</strong> 1951, 33% of those <strong>in</strong> wage<br />

employment worked on white owned farms; <strong>in</strong> the 1990s agricultural wage work accounts for<br />

less than 10% of those work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> South Africa (Agrifutura 1996). The reasons for the lower<br />

number of agricultural workers despite far greater volumes of production is complex <strong>and</strong><br />

geographically varied (Marcus 1989); nevertheless, the rapid mechanisation <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>dustrialisation of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> the late 1960s was almost certa<strong>in</strong>ly responsible for the lion’s<br />

share of these decl<strong>in</strong>es. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>agriculture</strong>’s contribution to exports, <strong>and</strong> therefore to the<br />

country’s balance of payments, has also decl<strong>in</strong>ed as a percentage of total exports. While the<br />

value of agricultural exports was over 10% <strong>in</strong> the 1970s, it has s<strong>in</strong>ce decl<strong>in</strong>ed to 4% <strong>in</strong> the<br />

1990s. Based on figures related to <strong>agriculture</strong>’s direct contribution to the South African<br />

economy, the <strong>post</strong>-war period has seen the sector’s importance <strong>in</strong> the economy decl<strong>in</strong>e<br />

significantly.<br />

The impact of the droughts on the economy suggests that <strong>agriculture</strong>’s role <strong>in</strong> the<br />

economy is more complex (Van Zyl 1993; Van Zyl, van der Verver <strong>and</strong> Groenewald 1988).<br />

2<br />

2 St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g et al, 1996 argue that the level of <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> may even be worse than the PSLDS data suggest<br />

because of the survey’s small <strong>and</strong> biased sample <strong>in</strong> the country’s poorest <strong>rural</strong> areas. The study also<br />

sampled a very small number of farm workers, a group identified as the poorest sector of the <strong>rural</strong><br />

population <strong>in</strong> previous <strong>poverty</strong> studies.


Dur<strong>in</strong>g the drought of the 1990s, economists calculated that low agricultural yields negatively<br />

affected GDP growth by between 0.5 <strong>and</strong> 2%, a stagger<strong>in</strong>g figure for a sector which is<br />

apparently play<strong>in</strong>g a relatively small role <strong>in</strong> the economy. In higher ra<strong>in</strong>fall years the impact<br />

of <strong>agriculture</strong> on the economy is equally significant, but <strong>in</strong> the opposite direction: <strong>in</strong> 1994, a<br />

year of above average ra<strong>in</strong>fall, a 16.3% rise <strong>in</strong> gross farm <strong>in</strong>come caused the economy to grow<br />

for the first time s<strong>in</strong>ce 1989 (F<strong>in</strong>ancial Mail 27 May 1994). The <strong>in</strong>direct role of agricultural<br />

production on growth is a function of the strong forward <strong>and</strong> backward l<strong>in</strong>kages <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

has with the rest of the economy. Fertiliser, chemical <strong>and</strong> implement manufacturers are<br />

dependent on a grow<strong>in</strong>g agricultural economy. In the 1993/4 season, for <strong>in</strong>stance, farmers<br />

spent over R500 million on pack<strong>in</strong>g material, R1.6 billion on fuel, R1.18 billion on fertilizers<br />

<strong>and</strong> R1 billion on dips <strong>and</strong> sprays (Abstract of Agricultural Statistics 1995). Many of these<br />

companies are dependent on the sale of chemicals <strong>and</strong> mach<strong>in</strong>ery to farmers. There are also<br />

important forward l<strong>in</strong>kages between <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry. In the early 1990s, only 34% of<br />

what farmers produced was consumed directly; the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g 66% was processed <strong>in</strong> some<br />

form by the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector.<br />

Economists have spent considerable effort specify<strong>in</strong>g the larger <strong>in</strong>direct role of<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> the economy by exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the forward <strong>and</strong> backward l<strong>in</strong>kages between<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> other sectors through <strong>in</strong>put-output analysis (van Zyl <strong>and</strong> V<strong>in</strong>k 1988; van<br />

Seventer, Faux, van Zyl 1992) <strong>and</strong> by simulat<strong>in</strong>g the impact of periodic droughts on growth<br />

<strong>and</strong> employment (Pretorius <strong>and</strong> Smal 1992; van Zyl et al, 1988). In 1995 the total agricultural<br />

output was almost R39 billion. To produce this amount of output, the sector’s dependent on<br />

<strong>in</strong>puts from non-agricultural sectors of the economy was equivalent to 43.4% of its total<br />

value of output, especially from the food sector, <strong>in</strong>dustrial chemicals <strong>and</strong> other chemical<br />

sectors, <strong>and</strong> the trade, cater<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> accommodation sector. Remuneration of employees <strong>and</strong><br />

gross operat<strong>in</strong>g surplus constituted 11.7% <strong>and</strong> 36.7% of the value of total output,<br />

respectively. On the expenditure side, domestic agricultural outputs provided for 93.3% of<br />

total expenditure on this sector’s products <strong>in</strong> 1995. The largest dem<strong>and</strong> for agricultural<br />

sector’s outputs comes from the <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>put needs of the non-agricultural sectors of<br />

the economy amount<strong>in</strong>g to 56.5% of total expenditure on agricultural products <strong>in</strong> 1995.<br />

Other major consumers of agricultural products were the domestic private consumption<br />

(28.7%) <strong>and</strong> exports (13%).<br />

This <strong>in</strong>terdependency between <strong>agriculture</strong> sector <strong>and</strong> the rest of the economy has been<br />

the basis of the empirical evidence that <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> agricultural production have large positive<br />

impacts on growth, employment <strong>and</strong> the balance of payments. Us<strong>in</strong>g the 1995 <strong>in</strong>put output<br />

table of South Africa, our calculation shows that for every R1 million of autonomous<br />

expenditure on agricultural production, the agricultural output <strong>in</strong>creases by R1.38 million<br />

while the overall economic output <strong>in</strong>creases by R6.51 million. This means that for every R1<br />

million of expenditure on agricultural production, an equivalent of extra R4.13 million is<br />

generated <strong>in</strong> other sectors of the economy. Agriculture also has a strong multiplier effect on<br />

employment. Our evaluation of the sectoral employment multipliers for the year 1995<br />

confirms the recent study by the Department of Agriculture (1996) <strong>and</strong> the earlier study by<br />

van Zyl <strong>and</strong> V<strong>in</strong>k (1988) that more jobs are created <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> with <strong>in</strong>creased production<br />

than for any other sector of the economy. Specifically, the effect of a R1 million <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong><br />

expenditure on agricultural production is an overall economy-wide employment <strong>in</strong>crease of<br />

75 persons which is divided between direct employment <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the <strong>agriculture</strong> sector of<br />

30 persons <strong>and</strong> an extra 45 employees <strong>in</strong> the rest of the economy. Simulations of drought on<br />

employment reveals how vulnerable farm workers are to low ra<strong>in</strong>fall <strong>and</strong> crop failure.<br />

Pretorius <strong>and</strong> Smal (1992) estimated that the direct impact of the 1992 drought on<br />

agricultural employment was a loss of 49,000 jobs. They also predicted that an additional<br />

3


20,000 people would lose their jobs <strong>in</strong> non-agricultural formal employment due to the<br />

<strong>in</strong>direct impact of <strong>agriculture</strong> on other sectors of the economy. F<strong>in</strong>ally, agricultural<br />

production has an important impact on the country’s balance of payments through imports<br />

<strong>and</strong> exports. In ‘normal’ ra<strong>in</strong>fall years, food constitutes only around 2% of total imports; <strong>in</strong> a<br />

drought year this figure is closer to 5% of total imports. The impact of the disastrous<br />

droughts of the early 1990s on balance of payments - through losses <strong>in</strong> export earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong><br />

the purchase of food on overseas markets - was over R1.2 billion for maize alone.<br />

The potential for <strong>agriculture</strong> to contribute to growth <strong>and</strong> employment given its large<br />

<strong>in</strong>direct role <strong>in</strong> the economy has been <strong>in</strong>terpreted <strong>in</strong> different ways. The World Bank’s<br />

analysis is that l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> market<strong>in</strong>g policies which discrim<strong>in</strong>ated aga<strong>in</strong>st Africans but <strong>in</strong>volved<br />

a huge transfer of resources to white farmers, led to a commercial agricultural sector<br />

dom<strong>in</strong>ated by capital <strong>in</strong>tensive, large scale <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficient farm<strong>in</strong>g units. While the apartheid<br />

goal of self-sufficiency <strong>in</strong> food products was achieved, it came at an enormous social,<br />

environmental <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial cost: “...society has been deprived of a greater contribution to<br />

GDP that a more efficient <strong>and</strong> dynamic agricultural sector would provide” (World Bank<br />

1994, xi). Their alternative is a l<strong>and</strong> reform programme that concentrates on <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong><br />

the former bantustans <strong>and</strong> the redistribution of l<strong>and</strong>, through market mechanisms, both of<br />

which should lead to the creation of a class of ‘emerg<strong>in</strong>g farmers’ who will use resources<br />

more efficiently <strong>and</strong> employ more <strong>rural</strong> people. The process of ‘downsiz<strong>in</strong>g’ farm size,<br />

accord<strong>in</strong>g to the World Bank, will lead to “...a more dynamic <strong>rural</strong> economy <strong>and</strong> to greater<br />

employment <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>come creation among low-<strong>in</strong>come groups” (ibid 155). Through l<strong>and</strong><br />

distribution <strong>and</strong> better extension programmes, black smallholders are the key to the World<br />

Bank’s programme for transform<strong>in</strong>g <strong>agriculture</strong> from a sector that played a central role <strong>in</strong> the<br />

immiseration of millions of <strong>rural</strong> people to one which leads to growth <strong>and</strong> job creation for<br />

the <strong>rural</strong> poor. 3<br />

The Merg policy placed a very different emphasis on the potential of <strong>agriculture</strong> for job<br />

creation <strong>and</strong> growth. They s<strong>in</strong>gled out <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> agro-<strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>and</strong> social <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

as the key macroeconomic <strong>strategies</strong> for growth <strong>and</strong> job creation <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> South Africa.<br />

Before the 1994 elections, target<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> agro-<strong>in</strong>dustry was also the ‘declared policy’<br />

of the ANC (Merg 1993). Their analysis was based on the ‘manufactur<strong>in</strong>g-agricultural<br />

complex’ (MAC), a group of agricultural <strong>and</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sectors that reflected <strong>agriculture</strong>’s<br />

contribution to reflect the strong l<strong>in</strong>ks between farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> other <strong>in</strong>dustrial sectors. The<br />

MAC <strong>in</strong>cludes food products, beverages, liquor <strong>and</strong> tobacco; textiles garments, leather<br />

products; wood, wood products, furniture; pulp, paper, pr<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> publish<strong>in</strong>g; <strong>and</strong> fertilizer<br />

<strong>and</strong> pesticides. This exp<strong>and</strong>ed def<strong>in</strong>ition reveals the extent of <strong>agriculture</strong>’s <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>in</strong> the<br />

economy: the MAC accounted for 28% of the employment normally def<strong>in</strong>ed under<br />

manufactur<strong>in</strong>g, 31% of the value generated by manufacturers <strong>and</strong> 25% of manufactur<strong>in</strong>g’s<br />

contribution to gross domestic product. The importance of the MAC is based on the labour<br />

<strong>in</strong>tensity of these sectors as well as the ‘dynamic <strong>in</strong>teractions’ that are possible between it <strong>and</strong><br />

other branches of the economy. For <strong>in</strong>stance, while farmers supply raw materials to<br />

manufacturers <strong>and</strong> also consume agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts like fertilizers, chemicals <strong>and</strong> pack<strong>in</strong>g<br />

material, very few other manufactured goods are consumed <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas. Indeed, only 3%<br />

of what is manufactured <strong>in</strong> South Africa is consumed by farmers <strong>and</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> mass market<br />

(Faux 1990). Chemical <strong>and</strong> fertilizer manufacturers have also appear to be optimistic about<br />

the prospects of a new class of small black farmers who “will create <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g prospects for<br />

the distribution of agricultural chemicals” (F<strong>in</strong>ancial Mail 27 May 1994). A policy which<br />

4<br />

3 Gav<strong>in</strong> Williams has written a detailed <strong>and</strong> trenchant critique of the World Bank’s proposals for <strong>rural</strong><br />

South Africa, see Williams (1996).


targets agro-<strong>in</strong>dustry, creates new jobs <strong>and</strong> improves <strong>rural</strong> livelihoods, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Merg, has<br />

the potential of stimulat<strong>in</strong>g the economy as a whole:<br />

Dynamic <strong>in</strong>teractions may be anticipated between exp<strong>and</strong>ed dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

the agricultural sector, <strong>in</strong>creased agro-<strong>in</strong>dustry output <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

output from a range of other manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sub-sectors. Grow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

output <strong>and</strong> rates of capacity utilisation, especially <strong>in</strong> the food process<strong>in</strong>g<br />

components of agro-<strong>in</strong>dustry should lower the real price of basic goods,<br />

result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the proportion of their <strong>in</strong>comes that the mass<br />

of the <strong>rural</strong> population can devote to the purchase of manufactures<br />

(Merg 1993, 170).<br />

The International Labour Office’s (ILO) report on labour markets <strong>in</strong> South Africa has<br />

pursued this argument <strong>in</strong> more detail, but also <strong>in</strong> the context of a better underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g of<br />

<strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>rural</strong> livelihoods (St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g et al 1996). Us<strong>in</strong>g the PSLSD data, as well as<br />

other surveys which seem more representative of the <strong>in</strong>come earn<strong>in</strong>g <strong>strategies</strong> of the <strong>rural</strong><br />

poor, they support Merg’s emphasis on <strong>rural</strong> job creation <strong>and</strong> the possibilities it has for the<br />

economy as a whole. The recent surveys suggest that <strong>in</strong>come from agricultural wage<br />

employment - however poorly paid <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>secure - rema<strong>in</strong>s the most important livelihood<br />

strategy for the <strong>rural</strong> poor <strong>and</strong> especially <strong>rural</strong> women. Income generated from the <strong>in</strong>formal<br />

sector <strong>and</strong> from farm<strong>in</strong>g represent a negligible portion of the total <strong>in</strong>come earned by poor<br />

<strong>rural</strong> households. The PSLSD profile of the households that do earn an <strong>in</strong>come from<br />

farm<strong>in</strong>g is very significant. It suggests that those households mak<strong>in</strong>g money from <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

also earn <strong>in</strong>come from the primary labour market, <strong>in</strong> other words jobs that are relatively<br />

secure <strong>and</strong> well paid. In contrast, the poorest <strong>rural</strong> households are unable to generate <strong>in</strong>come<br />

from agricultural production <strong>and</strong> rely <strong>in</strong>stead on wage <strong>in</strong>come from farm work or domestic<br />

service (May, Carter <strong>and</strong> Posel 1995). The importance of <strong>rural</strong> wage work is given further<br />

weight by the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g that remittances to <strong>rural</strong> households come ma<strong>in</strong>ly from wages earned<br />

with<strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas. This overturns the conventional wisdom that remittances to <strong>rural</strong><br />

households are transferred from wage earners located <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> metropolitan areas <strong>and</strong><br />

strengthens the case for a policy which improves <strong>rural</strong> employment opportunities.<br />

The Merg/ILO approach depends, of course, on improv<strong>in</strong>g work<strong>in</strong>g conditions <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong><br />

areas <strong>and</strong> especially employment practices on white commercial farms. While workers <strong>in</strong><br />

agro-process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries <strong>and</strong> forest plantations are often organised <strong>and</strong> enjoy competitive<br />

wages <strong>and</strong> adequate work<strong>in</strong>g conditions, wages for farm workers are notoriously low, work<strong>in</strong>g<br />

hours extend beyond the legal limit, <strong>and</strong> violence rema<strong>in</strong>s a form of coercion on some farms.<br />

On farms <strong>in</strong> the former bantustans conditions are variable: while sugar cane farmers <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Mpumalanga lowveld pay wages to farm labour <strong>and</strong> apparently have ‘good relations’ with<br />

their workers (Vaughan <strong>and</strong> McIntosh 1995), <strong>in</strong> other regions of the country, conditions are<br />

worse <strong>and</strong> payment <strong>in</strong> k<strong>in</strong>d appears to be the most common form of remuneration. The<br />

recent extension of the Labour Relations Act (LRA) to farm workers has focused attention<br />

on the possibilities of organis<strong>in</strong>g farm workers with a view to improv<strong>in</strong>g work<strong>in</strong>g conditions<br />

<strong>and</strong> wages (Murphy 1995). Unfortunately, the experience of unions has been disappo<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>g:<br />

it has proved extremely difficult to organise farm workers <strong>in</strong> the context of high <strong>rural</strong><br />

unemployment, <strong>and</strong> farmer reluctance to permit organisers access to workers. The South<br />

African Agricultural Union <strong>and</strong> the National Department of Agriculture have come out<br />

aga<strong>in</strong>st labour legislation, argu<strong>in</strong>g that it will encourage farmers to decrease the number of<br />

workers on farms <strong>and</strong> accelerate the trend away from maize production (Nampo 1993;<br />

Department of Agriculture 1996). And while the LRA may make it easier for unions to<br />

organise workers, commercial farmers rema<strong>in</strong> protected by pieces of legislation like the<br />

Trespass Act, which they can use to evict union organisers from their l<strong>and</strong>. Those farms that<br />

5


are organised have normally had the cooperation of the owner. They also tend to be larger<br />

operations - ‘factory farms’ - <strong>and</strong> often grow labour <strong>in</strong>tensive crops like citrus, deciduous fruit<br />

<strong>and</strong> vegetables. It has been far more difficult for unions to organise workers on smaller <strong>and</strong><br />

less labour <strong>in</strong>tensive farms.<br />

The ILO’s macroeconomic solution to <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> (St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g et al 1996, 262) - “that<br />

tackl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> requires <strong>in</strong>terventions to improve the wages <strong>and</strong> work<strong>in</strong>g conditions of<br />

the unemployed, as well as policies designed to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>and</strong> widen access to <strong>rural</strong> wage<br />

employment opportunities” - depends on the ability of unions to improve conditions <strong>and</strong> on<br />

the effectiveness of state <strong>in</strong>terventions to realise the ‘dynamic l<strong>in</strong>kages’ between <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> the rest of the economy. Significantly, unlike the World Bank approach, it depends<br />

much less on the potential of an emerg<strong>in</strong>g class of black farmers. How does Gear propose to<br />

alleviate <strong>and</strong> ultimately eradicate <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong>?<br />

Gear <strong>and</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

Gear has an impressive set of goals which <strong>in</strong>clude a projected 6 percent per annum<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> the creation of 400,000 jobs per annum by the year 2000. The success of the<br />

strategy is based on two ma<strong>in</strong> pillars, the transformation to a globally competitive, outward<br />

oriented economy <strong>and</strong> the creation of a stable economic <strong>and</strong> political environment for<br />

private <strong>in</strong>vestment. The growth of exports will be based on a powerful ‘expansion <strong>in</strong> the<br />

tradeable goods sector.’ This export sector will play a crucial role towards realis<strong>in</strong>g the targets<br />

of 6% GDP growth <strong>and</strong> 400,000 jobs per annum by the year 2000. The state’s role <strong>in</strong> this<br />

expansionary thrust is facilitatory: it will set up preferential trade agreements with large<br />

<strong>in</strong>ternational trad<strong>in</strong>g blocks, it will assist <strong>in</strong> open<strong>in</strong>g new markets for exports, <strong>and</strong> it will<br />

encourage greater regional economic <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>in</strong> Southern Africa. It will also ensure a<br />

stable exchange rate <strong>and</strong> will conta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>flation to provide the necessary stability for ‘a<br />

concerted expansion of export <strong>in</strong>dustries.’ The second policy <strong>in</strong>itiative to enable an outward<br />

oriented economy <strong>in</strong>volves remov<strong>in</strong>g a series of ‘constra<strong>in</strong>ts’ which, once elim<strong>in</strong>ated, will<br />

‘catapult the economy to the higher levels of growth, development <strong>and</strong> employment needed<br />

to provide a better life for all South Africans’. One of these constra<strong>in</strong>ts is tariffs on imported<br />

goods <strong>and</strong> the strategy commits itself to tariff liberalisation with a view to controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>put<br />

costs, conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>flation, stimulat<strong>in</strong>g foreign <strong>in</strong>vestment, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>directly contribut<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

more moderate wage dem<strong>and</strong>s. Tariffs <strong>and</strong> subsidies have <strong>in</strong> the past, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Gear, had<br />

the effect of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g producer prices; their <strong>in</strong>tention is to shift the focus towards ‘supply<br />

side measures designed to lower consumer costs <strong>and</strong> expedite progress up the value cha<strong>in</strong>’.<br />

To this end the strategy will not only half the number of tariff l<strong>in</strong>es, it will also abolish import<br />

surcharges <strong>and</strong> proceed with the phas<strong>in</strong>g out of the general export <strong>in</strong>centive scheme. The<br />

implications of these <strong>in</strong>itiatives for manufacturers will apparently be lower <strong>in</strong>put prices <strong>and</strong><br />

therefore more competitive products for local <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational markets.<br />

While domestic agricultural policies do not feature as one of the ‘constra<strong>in</strong>ts’ hamper<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the economy, the implications of the policy for <strong>agriculture</strong> are clear. Tariffs, subsidies, quotas<br />

<strong>and</strong> exchange controls played an important role <strong>in</strong> prevent<strong>in</strong>g farmers from becom<strong>in</strong>g export<br />

oriented <strong>and</strong>, together with the policy of apartheid, ensured that <strong>agriculture</strong> rema<strong>in</strong>ed focused<br />

on local markets to ensure national self-sufficiency (Fallon <strong>and</strong> Pereira da Silva 1994). It is<br />

very unlikely that the strategy will reverse the erosion - that has occurred s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1980s - of<br />

these <strong>in</strong>terventions <strong>in</strong> the ‘market’; on the contrary, it almost certa<strong>in</strong>ly implies that this<br />

erosion should be accelerated as part of a process lead<strong>in</strong>g to an agricultural sector that is<br />

more export oriented.<br />

6


Private <strong>in</strong>vestment is the second thrust of Gear <strong>and</strong> it calls for the brisk expansion of<br />

private sector capital formation. Several of the <strong>strategies</strong> identified earlier which were<br />

important for export growth - controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>flation, exchange control reforms, limit<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

volatility of the R<strong>and</strong>, as well as permitt<strong>in</strong>g foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors access to domestic credit - will<br />

be used to encourage more private <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the economy. Foreign <strong>and</strong> local <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

is to play an important part <strong>in</strong> Gear’s goal of 6% GDP growth by 2000 <strong>and</strong> considerable<br />

effort will go towards conv<strong>in</strong>c<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors on the stability of the economy, the state’s<br />

commitment towards a free market economy, <strong>and</strong> its approach towards budget reforms <strong>and</strong><br />

tight fiscal control. The emphasis on private <strong>in</strong>vestment must be seen <strong>in</strong> the context of the<br />

level <strong>and</strong> direction of public <strong>in</strong>vestment dur<strong>in</strong>g apartheid. Total public expenditure <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

from 31% of GDP <strong>in</strong> the period between 1978 <strong>and</strong> 1982 to 37% <strong>in</strong> 1992 (Fallon <strong>and</strong> Pereira<br />

da Silva 1994). This <strong>in</strong>vestment was, however, focused on ‘strategic sectors’ of the economy<br />

<strong>and</strong> on improv<strong>in</strong>g the ‘quantity <strong>and</strong> quality of services for the white m<strong>in</strong>ority.’ Accord<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

the World Bank this <strong>in</strong>vestment had a negligible impact on the economic performance of the<br />

economy. Gear’s emphasis on reduc<strong>in</strong>g public sector expenditure <strong>and</strong> on <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g private<br />

sector <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the economy represents a reversal of the wasteful <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficient nature<br />

of state expenditure dur<strong>in</strong>g apartheid.<br />

Despite the strategy’s focus on fiscal constra<strong>in</strong>t <strong>and</strong> budgetary reform, there are sectors<br />

of the economy which will receive direct state attention ‘<strong>in</strong> keep<strong>in</strong>g with RDP objectives.’<br />

The three areas highlighted <strong>in</strong> Gear are education; health <strong>and</strong> welfare; <strong>and</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g, l<strong>and</strong><br />

reform <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure. L<strong>and</strong> reform, the construction <strong>and</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>tenance of <strong>rural</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong> assistance to ‘emerg<strong>in</strong>g’ farmers are the <strong>strategies</strong> which appear to be<br />

directed towards improv<strong>in</strong>g the livelihoods of the <strong>rural</strong> poor. L<strong>and</strong> reform policies <strong>in</strong>clude<br />

asset redistribution, enhancement of tenure, the release of more l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>troduction of<br />

a ‘settlement’ grant. Small ‘emerg<strong>in</strong>g’ farmers represent the cornerstone of l<strong>and</strong> reform <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> this sense the document is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the World Bank’s<br />

emphasis on this sector: “...agricultural development associated with l<strong>and</strong> reform will play a<br />

key role <strong>in</strong> improv<strong>in</strong>g the distribution of <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> economic activity” (Republic of South<br />

Africa 1996, 15). The role of small farmers was re-emphasised <strong>in</strong> the most recent budget; the<br />

budget vote for <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong>cludes a special grant for small farmers to assist them <strong>in</strong><br />

improv<strong>in</strong>g their ‘production efficiency’ through <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong> tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. New emerg<strong>in</strong>g<br />

farmers will, however, soon need to be prepared for the rigours of a neoliberal<br />

macroeconomic environment. State assistance to farmers will shift from direct support <strong>in</strong><br />

the form of settlement <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> grants to <strong>in</strong>direct assistance <strong>in</strong> market<strong>in</strong>g, appropriate<br />

technology development, <strong>and</strong> streaml<strong>in</strong>ed extension. This shift is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with a policy that<br />

prepares new farmers for an open economy <strong>and</strong> a public <strong>in</strong>vestment programme that is<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ed by strict budget deficit targets.<br />

It is remarkable that Gear ignores the possible role of commercial <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> South<br />

Africa given its prom<strong>in</strong>ent, albeit <strong>in</strong>direct, role <strong>in</strong> the economy. Moreover, Gear fails to<br />

recognise the potential this sector has for economic growth <strong>and</strong> job creation, particularly <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>rural</strong> areas. Indeed, despite the depth of <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> South Africa, Gear emphasises the<br />

role of (urban-based) manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> the export of manufactured goods <strong>in</strong> reach<strong>in</strong>g its<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> employment goals. This is <strong>in</strong> direct contrast to earlier macroeconomic policy<br />

formulations, most notably those proposed by Merg <strong>and</strong> those outl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> a recent ILO<br />

report (Merg 1993; St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g et al 1996). Gear ignores the features of the manufactur<strong>in</strong>gagricultural<br />

complex - its labour <strong>in</strong>tensity <strong>and</strong> the potential for dynamic l<strong>in</strong>kages with other<br />

sectors of the economy - which made it an obvious target for <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the ANC’s preelection<br />

economic th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> a central component of the Merg <strong>and</strong> ILO macroeconomic<br />

policy formulations. Gear’s emphasis on the potential for manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustrial<br />

exports for job creation <strong>and</strong> growth is also puzzl<strong>in</strong>g given the experience of exports <strong>in</strong> the<br />

7


1980s <strong>and</strong> 1990s. While non-gold exports <strong>in</strong>creased by just over 5% <strong>in</strong> the period between<br />

the mid-1980s <strong>and</strong> 1993, agricultural exports have grown much faster <strong>in</strong> the same period.<br />

Agricultural exports have <strong>in</strong>creased by more than 8% a year <strong>in</strong> the 1990s <strong>and</strong> show the<br />

potential for <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g even more rapidly <strong>in</strong> the late 1990s (Adelzadeh 1996a; Agrifutura<br />

1996).<br />

The omission of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> the macroeconomy is of particular concern <strong>in</strong> the light of<br />

Bell’s (1996) recent analysis of the relative <strong>in</strong>fluence of domestic agricultural policies on<br />

agricultural production. The analysis is based on a careful assessment of the World Bank’s<br />

argument on the damag<strong>in</strong>g role of domestic farm<strong>in</strong>g policies on agricultural productivity <strong>and</strong><br />

on the sector’s contribution to the broader economy. The Bank’s argument is that decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

levels of productivity on the l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the small contribution of farm<strong>in</strong>g to GDP is a<br />

consequence of distorted domestic agricultural policies <strong>and</strong> the huge, but <strong>in</strong>efficient, transfer<br />

of resources to large scale white commercial farmers. As noted earlier, the World Bank’s<br />

position is that this trend can be reversed if resources are transferred to more efficient small<br />

scale farmers (World Bank 1994). A careful read<strong>in</strong>g of the data on agricultural productivity,<br />

especially after the mid-1980s when subsidies to white farmers <strong>and</strong> ‘distort<strong>in</strong>g policies’ were<br />

progressively removed, suggests that it is difficult to l<strong>in</strong>k domestic policies to agricultural<br />

productivity <strong>in</strong> any systematic or causal way. Bell (1996) suggests that local <strong>and</strong> global<br />

macroeconomic forces, rather than domestic agricultural policies, had a much more<br />

important role <strong>in</strong> shap<strong>in</strong>g the direction of farm<strong>in</strong>g productivity <strong>in</strong> the decades after 1970.<br />

The implication of this argument is extremely significant to debates on the potential of the<br />

manufactur<strong>in</strong>g-<strong>agriculture</strong> complex <strong>in</strong> job creation <strong>and</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation: it suggests that <strong>in</strong><br />

the face of an unfavourable macroeconomic environment, domestic policies which are aimed<br />

at encourag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>agriculture</strong> to play a role <strong>in</strong> job creation <strong>and</strong> redistribution may flounder.<br />

Bell’s argument on the importance of the macroeconomic environment <strong>and</strong> the relatively<br />

weak role of domestic policies <strong>in</strong> an unfavourable macroeconomy is not unique to South<br />

Africa. In a variety of Lat<strong>in</strong> American <strong>and</strong> African countries, domestic farm<strong>in</strong>g policies have<br />

been unable to compensate for macroeconomic policies which are unfavourable to<br />

agricultural production (e.g. Jaffee 1993).<br />

Although it is difficult to account for the enormous differences between Gear <strong>and</strong><br />

earlier formulations that were <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with ANC th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g, it is nevertheless an important<br />

measure of how far ANC economic th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g shifted <strong>in</strong> the last five years. And while the<br />

policy is largely silent on the possible role of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> agribus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> job creation <strong>and</strong><br />

growth, it is possible to explore the impact of an open, export oriented economy on<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> small scale farmers, the group of people Gear has identified as key to the<br />

alleviation of <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong>.<br />

8<br />

Export Oriented Economy<br />

One of the ma<strong>in</strong> pillars of Gear is the transformation of the economy from its <strong>in</strong>ward<br />

oriented focus to an outward oriented, export driven economy. While Gear ignores the<br />

potential of agricultural exports <strong>in</strong> job creation <strong>and</strong> growth, its broad emphasis on export<br />

orientation is, co<strong>in</strong>cidentally, <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the sub-sectors of <strong>agriculture</strong> that have the greatest<br />

potential for employment creation <strong>and</strong> growth. Exports of high value foods - vegetables,<br />

citrus, grapes <strong>and</strong> deciduous fruit - are exp<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g much more rapidly than field crops like<br />

maize, wheat <strong>and</strong> oilseeds, the traditional strength of the agricultural economy (Agrifutura<br />

1996). In the period s<strong>in</strong>ce the rapid devaluation of the R<strong>and</strong>, foreign exchange earn<strong>in</strong>gs from<br />

fruit exports have risen sharply <strong>and</strong> revenues can be expected to <strong>in</strong>crease further. These<br />

crops are also far more labour <strong>in</strong>tensive than other food <strong>and</strong> fibre crops <strong>and</strong> the number of


workers <strong>in</strong> this subsector has <strong>in</strong>creased, or rema<strong>in</strong>ed steady, <strong>in</strong> the face of sharp decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong><br />

overall agricultural employment levels. Horticultural farmers employ more labour at higher<br />

wage rates than field crops <strong>and</strong> animal products, the other two ma<strong>in</strong> agricultural sub-sectors<br />

(Abstract, Agricultural Statistics 1995). Indeed, irrigated <strong>agriculture</strong> requires five times more<br />

labour than for field crops (St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g et al 1996). Citrus farmers currently employ upwards of<br />

100,000 workers (Dixie 1995) <strong>and</strong> employment <strong>in</strong> the deciduous fruit sector is over 330,000<br />

(de Klerk 1996). Many of these farm workers are <strong>rural</strong> women, a category that most <strong>poverty</strong><br />

studies identify as be<strong>in</strong>g the poorest <strong>and</strong> most vulnerable group <strong>in</strong> South Africa. One of the<br />

reasons why employment levels have not decl<strong>in</strong>ed as rapidly is because harvest<strong>in</strong>g, plant<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>and</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g horticultural crops is less vulnerable to mechanisation. In contrast, the<br />

impact of mechanisation of field crops like maize, which has been well documented, has had<br />

far reach<strong>in</strong>g impacts on employment structure <strong>and</strong> overall levels of employment (de Klerk<br />

1984; Marcus 1989). Increas<strong>in</strong>g levels of mechanization, particularly <strong>in</strong> the period after the<br />

late 1960s, led to a sharp decrease <strong>in</strong> the overall workforce on maize farms. Casual <strong>and</strong><br />

seasonal workers, most of whom were women, were disproportionately affected by<br />

mechanization: while the numbers of permanent employees decreased by 20%, the number<br />

of casual employees dropped by as much as 50% on some farms. Although the labour<br />

process <strong>in</strong> horticulture is not immune to labour sav<strong>in</strong>g devices, many tasks, notably<br />

harvest<strong>in</strong>g soft <strong>and</strong> easily bruised fruit <strong>and</strong> vegetables, cannot be performed us<strong>in</strong>g a mach<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce export <strong>agriculture</strong> depends on irrigation, production levels - <strong>and</strong> by implication<br />

employment levels - are less vulnerable to periodic droughts which devastate other sectors of<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>. While the value of maize exports <strong>in</strong> 1994 - a year of exceptionally high ra<strong>in</strong>fall -<br />

was far higher than for all other crops, the value of maize exports varied wildly <strong>in</strong> the period<br />

between 1989 <strong>and</strong> 1994 (Figure 1). Citrus <strong>and</strong> deciduous fruit exports, <strong>in</strong> contrast, were far<br />

more stable <strong>and</strong> both experienced comparatively steady ga<strong>in</strong>s through the 1990s. The<br />

dislocation that farm workers experience when maize <strong>and</strong> other field crops fail due to<br />

drought, is less likely for farm workers on fruit, vegetable <strong>and</strong> citrus farms. The organisation<br />

of fruit, citrus <strong>and</strong> grape product market<strong>in</strong>g also places <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> a strong position to<br />

exp<strong>and</strong> exports. Market<strong>in</strong>g is organised by several large <strong>in</strong>terconnected monopolies which<br />

control the sophisticated <strong>in</strong>frastructure required to transport the crop from the farm to an<br />

overseas supermarket. Although the statutory monopoly these organisations have had over<br />

exports has been questioned or repealed, they have the resources <strong>and</strong> expertise to open new<br />

overseas markets <strong>in</strong> an extremely competitive <strong>in</strong>ternational environment.<br />

9<br />

Figure 1: Value of exports for selected<br />

(constant r<strong>and</strong>s)<br />

1800<br />

1600<br />

1400<br />

1200<br />

1000<br />

800<br />

R<strong>and</strong><br />

600<br />

400<br />

200<br />

0<br />

1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994<br />

Maize<br />

Citrus<br />

Deciduous fruit<br />

Year


10<br />

Despite not receiv<strong>in</strong>g the attention it arguably deserves from Gear, the high value<br />

agricultural export sector has the potential to contribute to <strong>rural</strong> job creation, foreign<br />

exchange earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> economic growth. Improv<strong>in</strong>g wage <strong>in</strong>come opportunities is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e<br />

with the ILO’s call for <strong>rural</strong> job creation programmes that benefit the poorest group <strong>in</strong> South<br />

Africa, <strong>rural</strong> women. Increas<strong>in</strong>g production by extend<strong>in</strong>g the l<strong>and</strong> under cultivation should<br />

have a direct impact on employment levels. The rapid growth of high value food exports <strong>in</strong><br />

Chile, Brazil <strong>and</strong> Taiwan played an important role <strong>in</strong> foreign exchange earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> <strong>rural</strong><br />

employment. Moreover, the growth of this high value food exports led to the growth of<br />

process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries, <strong>in</strong> other words the ‘dynamic <strong>in</strong>teractions’ that Merg<br />

policy makers hoped to encourage with <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> agro-<strong>in</strong>dustry. Any expectation that<br />

South African horticultural exports will experience the same k<strong>in</strong>d of rapid growth rates<br />

experienced <strong>in</strong> Chile, Brazil <strong>and</strong> Taiwan must, however, consider the global environment that<br />

permitted these countries to exp<strong>and</strong> their export <strong>in</strong>dustries so rapidly. A crucial feature of<br />

the growth of high value food exports <strong>in</strong> these countries dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s was the<br />

“...the very favourable <strong>in</strong>ternational market conditions dur<strong>in</strong>g their ‘take-off’ stage <strong>and</strong> for<br />

many subsequent years” (Jaffee 1993, 38). The large monopolistic market<strong>in</strong>g agents for<br />

deciduous fruit, citrus <strong>and</strong> w<strong>in</strong>e products <strong>in</strong> South Africa have had some success - particularly<br />

with the removal of sanctions - <strong>in</strong> penetrat<strong>in</strong>g new <strong>in</strong>ternational markets <strong>in</strong> the 1990s. In<br />

1996 <strong>and</strong> 1997 Outspan <strong>and</strong> Unifruco, the ma<strong>in</strong> market<strong>in</strong>g agents for citrus <strong>and</strong> deciduous<br />

fruits respectively, have negotiated access to the Canada <strong>and</strong> the United States, markets which<br />

were previously closed as part of the campaign to isolate South Africa dur<strong>in</strong>g apartheid.<br />

These notable successes must be set aga<strong>in</strong>st the more general trend towards the fierce<br />

protection of domestic markets <strong>and</strong> the strong farm<strong>in</strong>g lobby <strong>in</strong> most northern hemisphere<br />

countries.<br />

The recent trade negotiations between South Africa <strong>and</strong> the European Union has<br />

provided an important lesson <strong>in</strong> the difficulties of <strong>in</strong>ternational food <strong>and</strong> fibre trad<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Shortly after the 1994 elections, the EU offered South African exporters a trade agreement<br />

which was <strong>in</strong>tended to ‘reward’ the country for its successful democratic transition <strong>and</strong> to<br />

assist <strong>in</strong> reconstruction <strong>and</strong> development. Formal negotiations were delayed until June 1996,<br />

due ma<strong>in</strong>ly to France’s <strong>in</strong>sistence for an <strong>in</strong> depth study of the possible impact of a free trade<br />

agreement with South Africa (F<strong>in</strong>ancial Mail 8 March 1996). The <strong>in</strong>itial proposals have<br />

foundered <strong>in</strong> the face of the EU’s powerful farm<strong>in</strong>g lobby which <strong>in</strong>itially dem<strong>and</strong>ed that 48%<br />

of exist<strong>in</strong>g exports from South Africa to the EU be excluded from the free trade agreement.<br />

Under pressure from South Africa <strong>and</strong> from groups with<strong>in</strong> the EU the figure was amended<br />

to just over 38% of exports. Significantly, there are no restrictions for non-agricultural<br />

products under the proposed agreement <strong>and</strong> the products that will still be affected by tariffs<br />

<strong>in</strong>clude maize, grapes, w<strong>in</strong>e, deciduous fruit <strong>and</strong> processed fruit products. These restrictions<br />

are remarkable when consider<strong>in</strong>g the proportion of South Africa’s export to the total that the<br />

EU imports - a mere 1.51% - <strong>and</strong> the fact that local products are counter season (F<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

Mail 29 March, 1996). International competition may also limit the extent to which South<br />

African agricultural exports can exp<strong>and</strong>. Exporters are already compet<strong>in</strong>g with countries like<br />

Chile, Brazil, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Australia <strong>and</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a, all of whom have the same counter<br />

season advantage as South African growers. The cont<strong>in</strong>ued protection of domestic markets<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>ternational competition led a World Bank report on the citrus <strong>in</strong>dustry to<br />

predict a very modest 7% growth <strong>in</strong> citrus exports over the next decade (Dixie 1995). The<br />

potential for growth <strong>in</strong> high value food exports <strong>and</strong> by implications, employment growth,<br />

foreign exchange earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>and</strong> dynamic l<strong>in</strong>kages with other sectors of the economy depends<br />

on <strong>in</strong>ternational market conditions. International conditions may not permit the rapid<br />

expansion of exports as was the case for countries like Chile dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1970s <strong>and</strong> early<br />

1980s.


11<br />

The employment <strong>and</strong> growth potential associated with high value food exports must be<br />

weighed aga<strong>in</strong>st the costs of an open economy to farmers <strong>and</strong> farm workers produc<strong>in</strong>g field<br />

crops like maize, wheat <strong>and</strong> oil seeds for the domestic market. While exporters will emerge<br />

as w<strong>in</strong>ners <strong>in</strong> an open economy, the agricultural losers will be maize, wheat <strong>and</strong> oilseed<br />

farmers. Compet<strong>in</strong>g with maize <strong>and</strong> wheat imported from the United States or the European<br />

Union will be extremely difficult for South African farmers given the high subsidies <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>direct transfers that farmers cont<strong>in</strong>ue to enjoy. The United States, for <strong>in</strong>stance, has<br />

selected the South African market as part of its export promotion <strong>and</strong> subsidy programme<br />

under the ‘Export Promotion Programme.’ While WTO should theoretically open markets<br />

<strong>and</strong> promote freer trade <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>, it seems more likely that agricultural trade will simply<br />

be subject to new control <strong>and</strong> subsidy measures. Moreover, s<strong>in</strong>ce the provisions of the<br />

WTO are for tariff <strong>and</strong> subsidy reduction rather than the wholesale removal of trade barriers,<br />

the impact of freer trade depends on the <strong>in</strong>itial level of protection. Levels of protection have<br />

always been much higher <strong>in</strong> the United States <strong>and</strong> the European Union <strong>and</strong> they will therefor<br />

reta<strong>in</strong> higher subsidies under WTO regulations. Rather than promot<strong>in</strong>g freer trade, it seems<br />

that one of the impacts of the WTO will allow countries <strong>in</strong> North America <strong>and</strong> Europe<br />

greater access to the markets of develop<strong>in</strong>g countries to the detriment of local field crop<br />

producers <strong>and</strong> workers (Keet 1996).<br />

The dismantl<strong>in</strong>g of domestic subsidies <strong>and</strong> regulations <strong>in</strong> the period s<strong>in</strong>ce the mid-1980s<br />

has made field crop farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> South Africa even more vulnerable to imports. Producer<br />

subsidies <strong>and</strong> per capita transfers to <strong>agriculture</strong>, for example, are much lower for South<br />

African farmers than they are for farmers <strong>in</strong> Europe or the United States (Agrifutura 1996).<br />

Indeed, the entire regulatory environment for <strong>agriculture</strong> has changed radically with the<br />

amendment of agricultural market<strong>in</strong>g legislation, the withdrawal of direct state subsidies, <strong>and</strong><br />

the replacement of quantitative restrictions on food imports with tariffs <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the<br />

GATT. Dur<strong>in</strong>g most years, these differences will allow US farmers to deliver wheat <strong>and</strong><br />

animal feed to Cape Town at prices that are below production costs of the same crop <strong>in</strong><br />

South Africa (Williams 1996). In a more open economy, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the context of an agricultural<br />

policy which is committed to a ‘viable market-directed farm<strong>in</strong>g sector’, considerable<br />

restructur<strong>in</strong>g of maize, wheat <strong>and</strong> oilseed farm<strong>in</strong>g is likely to occur. The shift from maize<br />

farm<strong>in</strong>g to stock or game farm<strong>in</strong>g, a production regime that requires much less labour, will<br />

probably be hastened <strong>in</strong> this new regime. Employment creation <strong>and</strong> growth <strong>in</strong> this sector<br />

appears far less likely under Gear <strong>and</strong> uneven <strong>rural</strong> development is almost certa<strong>in</strong>ly one of the<br />

most important long term impacts of an open oriented economy. What private <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

does occur <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong> areas is likely to follow sectors with the potential for export earn<strong>in</strong>g<br />

rather than on those sectors focused on the local market. Job creation <strong>and</strong> growth <strong>in</strong> the<br />

long term is therefore far more likely <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> regions focused on exports: the Western Cape,<br />

parts of the Northern Prov<strong>in</strong>ce, Mpumalanga, Eastern <strong>and</strong> Northern Cape. In contrast, the<br />

maize <strong>and</strong> wheat grow<strong>in</strong>g regions of Mpumalanga, the Free State <strong>and</strong> the North West are<br />

likely to experience job losses <strong>and</strong> decl<strong>in</strong>e, especially <strong>in</strong> the context of a macroeconomic<br />

policy which puts such faith <strong>in</strong> private sector <strong>in</strong>vestment for growth <strong>and</strong> job creation. One<br />

of the more significant impacts of Gear will be the way it reshapes <strong>and</strong> transforms <strong>rural</strong><br />

economies <strong>and</strong> wage earn<strong>in</strong>g opportunities.<br />

The emphasis of both domestic agricultural <strong>and</strong> macroeconomic policies on exporters at<br />

the expense of farm<strong>in</strong>g that is focused on local consumption has important implications for<br />

food security <strong>and</strong> job creation, particularly <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries that are l<strong>in</strong>ked to farm<strong>in</strong>g through<br />

backward or forward l<strong>in</strong>kages. The apartheid government’s commitment to national food<br />

security is clearly no longer an important policy consideration at the domestic agricultural or<br />

the macroeconomic policy level <strong>and</strong> this shift is mirrored <strong>in</strong> numerous other policy papers


produced after 1994. Gear’s approach to food security is thus <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with <strong>strategies</strong> with<strong>in</strong><br />

other government departments. The implications of Gear on forward <strong>and</strong> backward l<strong>in</strong>kages<br />

are more complicated <strong>and</strong> perhaps more serious for job creation. As noted earlier <strong>in</strong> the<br />

paper <strong>agriculture</strong> has important backward <strong>and</strong> forward l<strong>in</strong>kages with other sectors of the<br />

economy which are labour <strong>in</strong>tensive. Although scant research has been done on the topic it<br />

is almost certa<strong>in</strong>ly the case that the employment l<strong>in</strong>kages are greater for sectors of <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

focused on the domestic market, sectors which are likely to come under <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g pressure<br />

<strong>in</strong> a neoliberal economic environment. If these sectors suffer from <strong>in</strong>creased competition<br />

then the important employment <strong>and</strong> growth l<strong>in</strong>kages with other sectors of the economy will<br />

be lost. Gear’s shortsightedness on the important <strong>in</strong>direct role of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> the economy<br />

may thus jeopardize the employment <strong>and</strong> growth capacity of those sectors with strong l<strong>in</strong>ks<br />

to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

If penetrat<strong>in</strong>g new markets may be difficult, organis<strong>in</strong>g farm workers <strong>and</strong> improv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

conditions is a more challeng<strong>in</strong>g prospect. Nonetheless, the prospect of alleviat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rural</strong><br />

<strong>poverty</strong> through agricultural wage work depends ultimately on improv<strong>in</strong>g conditions for farm<br />

workers. Organis<strong>in</strong>g farm workers <strong>and</strong> the spread of farm worker equity schemes are two<br />

immediate ways of improv<strong>in</strong>g wages <strong>and</strong> conditions on farms. Of the two, unionis<strong>in</strong>g farm<br />

workers is perhaps more challeng<strong>in</strong>g; as Murphy (1995, 20) has argued, “...the importance <strong>and</strong><br />

desirability of organis<strong>in</strong>g farmworkers will rema<strong>in</strong> rhetoric until the practical difficulties<br />

<strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> try<strong>in</strong>g to organise <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> are squarely addressed.” These obstacles <strong>in</strong>clude<br />

the spatial distribution of farm workers, the small number of workers on <strong>in</strong>dividual farms, the<br />

limited resources of unions, the persistence of paternalism on some farms (Waldman 1996;<br />

Krit<strong>in</strong>ger <strong>and</strong> Vorster 1996; du Toit 1994), <strong>and</strong> the active efforts of white farmers aga<strong>in</strong>st<br />

union efforts to organise farm workers. Even when worker protest has enjoyed limited<br />

success (e.g. Mather 1993), divisions with<strong>in</strong> the workforce have militated aga<strong>in</strong>st effective <strong>and</strong><br />

long-term organisation. In parts of the Western Cape, ethnic divisions are be<strong>in</strong>g exploited by<br />

fruit <strong>and</strong> w<strong>in</strong>e farmers with the express purpose of defend<strong>in</strong>g themselves aga<strong>in</strong>st unions. On<br />

these farms, the work force is divided between a better paid group of coloured men <strong>and</strong><br />

women who live permanently on the farm <strong>and</strong> apparently share the same consciousness as<br />

the white farmer, <strong>and</strong> a group of poorly paid seasonal black workers. This division ensures<br />

that resident workers are unlikely to be tempted by unions <strong>and</strong> excludes Africans who are<br />

perceived as the ‘union vanguard’ <strong>and</strong> more <strong>in</strong>cl<strong>in</strong>ed to militancy (Hamman <strong>and</strong> Ewert 1996).<br />

One solution to the problem of organis<strong>in</strong>g workers is to concentrate on farms where unions<br />

have had limited success: large, labour <strong>in</strong>tensive farms export<strong>in</strong>g high value food for export<br />

<strong>and</strong> employ<strong>in</strong>g upwards of 500 workers. Farm owners employ<strong>in</strong>g such large numbers are<br />

generally less reluctant see union organisation <strong>and</strong> some may even encourage unions with a<br />

view to <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g productivity levels. Greater leverage is possible with exporters - despite<br />

the reluctance of the WTO to <strong>in</strong>clude a clause which specifies work<strong>in</strong>g conditions on farms -<br />

who are vulnerable to <strong>in</strong>ternational pressure as was recently demonstrated <strong>in</strong> the w<strong>in</strong>e<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry. If unions could organise employees on large farms they would represent close to<br />

10% of all farm workers, a figure that is considerably higher than current estimates. In the<br />

Western Cape, for <strong>in</strong>stance, unions have organised approximately 18,000 workers, or only<br />

5.5% of the regions workers (Murphy 1995). A second solution which has had some success<br />

<strong>in</strong> the Transkei, is for unions to target outgrower schemes run by government parastatals.<br />

On these labour <strong>in</strong>tensive farms, unions have successfully <strong>in</strong>creased wages <strong>and</strong> improved<br />

worker conditions (Porter <strong>and</strong> Phillips-Howard 1996). The problem with both these<br />

<strong>strategies</strong> is that unions would be organis<strong>in</strong>g workers on farms where conditions <strong>and</strong> facilities<br />

are considerably better than the norm. It would also focus on permanent workers at the<br />

expense of seasonal workers, most of whom are women, <strong>and</strong> labour <strong>in</strong>tensive farms at the<br />

expense of workers on field crop <strong>and</strong> animal product farms. The prospects for farm workers<br />

12


on maize farms, where the average number of permanent workers per farm is 15 (Nampo<br />

1993), is much less promis<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Farm worker equity schemes, which <strong>in</strong>volve farm workers own<strong>in</strong>g part or all of the<br />

farm, is a second way of improv<strong>in</strong>g conditions <strong>and</strong> empower<strong>in</strong>g farm workers <strong>in</strong> high value<br />

food farm<strong>in</strong>g (McKenzie 1996; Nel, van Rooyen <strong>and</strong> Ngqangweni 1995). It is a method of<br />

redistribut<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>and</strong> without affect<strong>in</strong>g the structure of <strong>in</strong>dividual farms or overall production<br />

levels; <strong>in</strong>deed, with better job satisfaction <strong>and</strong> greater participation, productivity should<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease on farms where workers are also owners. Significantly, the share-equity schemes that<br />

have received the highest profile are produc<strong>in</strong>g high value food for export (Eckert, Hamman<br />

<strong>and</strong> Lombard 1996; Mail <strong>and</strong> Guardian 26 July 1996). On one farm <strong>in</strong> the Mpumalanga<br />

lowveld, the results of a share-equity scheme have been very impressive: wages <strong>in</strong>creased by<br />

250%, a day care center was built, <strong>and</strong> facilities for permanent <strong>and</strong> casual workers were<br />

improved (Mail <strong>and</strong> Guardian 26 July 1996). The cases that have been documented suggest<br />

that share-equity schemes must also <strong>in</strong>volve education <strong>and</strong> a commitment to participation <strong>in</strong><br />

decision mak<strong>in</strong>g (Eckert, Hamman <strong>and</strong> Lombard 1996). The number of equity schemes that<br />

have been reported are at this stage is very small (Nel, van Rooyen <strong>and</strong> Ngqangweni 1995);<br />

nevertheless if they spread <strong>and</strong> if they do empower farm workers, they have the potential of<br />

contribut<strong>in</strong>g to an overall strategy that improves conditions for <strong>rural</strong> wage workers.<br />

13<br />

Small scale farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

There is an enormous political will <strong>in</strong> South Africa for small scale black commercial<br />

farm<strong>in</strong>g (Vaughan <strong>and</strong> McIntosh 1993; Lipton 1996). The Department of F<strong>in</strong>ance’s 1997/8<br />

budget has set aside funds for loans to ‘emerg<strong>in</strong>g farmers’ <strong>and</strong> it has also started a ‘grant<br />

assistance scheme’ to help black farmers improve efficiency through <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>and</strong><br />

tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. In Gear, small scale farm<strong>in</strong>g is central to the campaign to fight <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong>. The<br />

World Bank has also put its not <strong>in</strong>considerable weight beh<strong>in</strong>d the drive to <strong>in</strong>crease the<br />

number of small scale farmers <strong>in</strong> the South African countryside (Williams 1996). This section<br />

attempts to address two questions about small scale farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> South Africa: how will<br />

‘emerg<strong>in</strong>g farmers’ fare under Gear <strong>and</strong> what impact will it have on <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong>?<br />

It was noted earlier that Gear’s assistance to small scale black farmers will be temporary<br />

<strong>and</strong> that they will not be protected from market forces through the subsidies <strong>and</strong> protection<br />

that white commercial farmers enjoyed for so long. Once emerg<strong>in</strong>g farmers have received an<br />

<strong>in</strong>itial grant, assistance will take the form of ‘streaml<strong>in</strong>ed extension’ <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the development<br />

of market<strong>in</strong>g <strong>strategies</strong>. There is, however, little recognition of the broader implications of<br />

the macroeconomic strategy might be for small scale farmers. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a fundamental<br />

component of Gear <strong>in</strong>volves controll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>flation by ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g high <strong>in</strong>terest rates; the real<br />

rate of <strong>in</strong>terest is between 8% <strong>and</strong> 10% <strong>and</strong> will almost certa<strong>in</strong>ly be ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed at that level <strong>in</strong><br />

the future. A high <strong>in</strong>terest rate will put severe limitations on the ability of small scale farmers<br />

to borrow money <strong>and</strong> enhance their ‘production efficiency.’ The similarities between Gear<br />

<strong>and</strong> a structural adjustment programme means that the <strong>in</strong>ternational experience of small<br />

farmers under structural adjustment must be <strong>in</strong>structive. Unfortunately, most cases studies<br />

suggest that <strong>in</strong> the absence of direct state <strong>in</strong>tervention, small scale farmers are less likely to<br />

succeed <strong>in</strong> a ‘free market’ environment (Acevedo, Barry <strong>and</strong> Rosa 1996; Carter <strong>and</strong> Barham<br />

1996; Sahn <strong>and</strong> Arulpragasam 1991; Due <strong>and</strong> Gladw<strong>in</strong> 1991). One of the more common<br />

results of structural adjustment is the concentration of production <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> fewer h<strong>and</strong>s<br />

(Morales 1991; Carter <strong>and</strong> Broham 1996; Korokv<strong>in</strong> 1992; Little <strong>and</strong> Watts 1994). The most<br />

promis<strong>in</strong>g smallholder schemes <strong>in</strong> South Africa <strong>in</strong>volve sugar cane farm<strong>in</strong>g for large<br />

processors <strong>in</strong> Kwa-Zulu/Natal <strong>and</strong> Mpumalanga. In the former region, the outgrowers are


organised by the private sector <strong>and</strong> there are approximately 30,000 black smallholders<br />

produc<strong>in</strong>g cane for local sugar process<strong>in</strong>g companies (Vaughan <strong>and</strong> McIntosh 1993). In<br />

Mpumalanga, sugar farm<strong>in</strong>g was developed with the active assistance of the former homel<strong>and</strong><br />

government which subsidised the preparation of l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the construction of irrigation<br />

equipment. The current prov<strong>in</strong>cial government has cont<strong>in</strong>ued to support the development<br />

of smallholder cane farmers <strong>in</strong> the region <strong>in</strong> response to the <strong>in</strong>creased dem<strong>and</strong> for sugar cane<br />

follow<strong>in</strong>g the construction of a second process<strong>in</strong>g plant <strong>in</strong> the region. Several writers have<br />

argued that irrigation represents the most effective way of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g smallholder production<br />

(Cooper 1991; Antonie <strong>and</strong> Bromberger 1992; Phillips-Howard <strong>and</strong> Porter 1996).<br />

Despite the apparent success of smallholder farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> parts of the country, ensur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

equity, access <strong>and</strong> susta<strong>in</strong>ability has proved difficult (c.f. Little <strong>and</strong> Watts 1994; Korovk<strong>in</strong><br />

1992). In their analysis of smallholder sugar cane production <strong>in</strong> Mpumalanga, for example,<br />

McIntosh <strong>and</strong> Vaughan (1995) reach an all too familiar conclusion: “...the fact rema<strong>in</strong>s that<br />

better-off people are likely to become commercial smallholders...the disadvantaged are most<br />

likely to lose access to their traditional arable hold<strong>in</strong>gs.” While the environmental<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>ability of these schemes has not been exam<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> detail, the record of smallholder<br />

schemes <strong>in</strong> bantustans has not been good (de Wet 1990). In the smallholder irrigation region<br />

of Mpumalanga there are serious concerns over water resources <strong>and</strong> the long term impact of<br />

high <strong>in</strong>put farm<strong>in</strong>g on fragile soils. The problem of resources is mirrored <strong>in</strong> the Western<br />

Cape where the potential for <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>and</strong> under irrigation is limited <strong>and</strong> problems of<br />

sal<strong>in</strong>isation <strong>and</strong> soil compaction are becom<strong>in</strong>g serious (Moolman <strong>and</strong> Lambrechts 1996).<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, the success of irrigation <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> Mpumalanga has come at great cost to the<br />

prov<strong>in</strong>cial government <strong>and</strong> has required direct state <strong>in</strong>tervention. Smallholder farm<br />

development is without question expensive (Lipton 1996). In the Transkei, the great<br />

potential for smallholder irrigation, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Phillips Howard <strong>and</strong> Porter (1996, 381)<br />

depends above all on “substantial state <strong>and</strong> donor <strong>in</strong>vestment.” Whether this expense is<br />

warranted - given the problems of equity <strong>and</strong> the fact that it will have a limited impact on<br />

<strong>rural</strong> unemployment (e.g. Vaughan <strong>and</strong> McIntosh 1995) - is one important policy question;<br />

another is whether the funds will be available <strong>in</strong> a macroeconomic environment which<br />

celebrates the free market <strong>and</strong> is constricted by fiscal austerity.<br />

International evidence suggests that smallholders have not fared well under a neoliberal<br />

economic environment. For <strong>in</strong>stance, the experience of maize farmers <strong>in</strong> Mexico, threatened<br />

by highly subsidised maize from the United States <strong>and</strong> Canada under the North America Free<br />

Trade Agreement, <strong>in</strong>dicates that the ability to respond effectively to <strong>in</strong>ternational competition<br />

depends on the scale of the operation <strong>and</strong> on direct state assistance (de Janvry, Sadoulet <strong>and</strong><br />

Gordillo de Anda 1995). While large farmers with access to credit <strong>and</strong> market<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions<br />

were able to diversify <strong>and</strong> modernize production, small farmers found themselves without<br />

<strong>in</strong>stitutional support <strong>in</strong> a marked driven economy. De Janvry et al (1995), argued that for<br />

small scale farmers, state assistance was vital, but <strong>in</strong> a neo-liberal macroeconomy, they were<br />

“...left largely destitute of <strong>in</strong>stitutional support, precisely at a time when they need full access<br />

to these services to modernize maize production <strong>and</strong> diversify cropp<strong>in</strong>g patterns towards<br />

higher value crops.” Writers on the impact of the neoliberal policy <strong>in</strong> South Africa have<br />

predicted a similar fate for small scale farmers. A few years ago Helena Dolny (1993 212)<br />

wrote that the impact of policy directions <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> would be to “...open itself up to<br />

operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a free market <strong>in</strong> which the rule of survival of the fittest will reign<br />

supreme...[<strong>and</strong>]...only those whose resources <strong>and</strong> production efficiency permit a cost<br />

competitiveness with the world market will rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> gra<strong>in</strong> farm<strong>in</strong>g.” More recently Gav<strong>in</strong><br />

Williams (1996, 174) has written that the “...removal of subsidies will not ‘level the play<strong>in</strong>g<br />

field’ between established large-scale farmers <strong>and</strong> smallholders <strong>in</strong> the former bantustans or<br />

ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g from l<strong>and</strong> redistribution. The abolition of pan-territorial prices <strong>in</strong> South Africa will<br />

14


enefit well situated farmers; most African producers will cont<strong>in</strong>ue to be relatively<br />

disadvantaged, even after a l<strong>and</strong> reform, by their distance from roads, railways <strong>and</strong> major<br />

markets.” Tea production <strong>in</strong> the former Transkei is one <strong>in</strong>dustry which will almost certa<strong>in</strong>ly<br />

do worse under a freer trad<strong>in</strong>g regime (Porter <strong>and</strong> Phillips-Howard 1996). Before GATT, a<br />

quota system protected producers by from cheaper imports; while contractors sold tea at<br />

between R12 <strong>and</strong> R14 per kilo, it was possible to import high quality tea for R8 per<br />

kilogramme. Porter <strong>and</strong> Phillips-Howard (1996) argue that tea production - <strong>and</strong> livelihoods<br />

<strong>and</strong> employment - <strong>in</strong> this region is extremely vulnerable to a more open trad<strong>in</strong>g regime. Gear<br />

places a large burden of responsibility <strong>in</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation on small scale farmers; whether<br />

small scale farmers will be able to grow to deliver on these high expectations <strong>in</strong> a neo-liberal<br />

<strong>and</strong> open macroeconomy is very much <strong>in</strong> doubt.<br />

De Janvry et al’s (1995) research on Mexico <strong>and</strong> the diversification of small scale farmers<br />

<strong>in</strong>to high value foods raises the question of the possibility of emerg<strong>in</strong>g farmers <strong>in</strong> South<br />

Africa participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the export of fruit, citrus <strong>and</strong> grape products. Citrus <strong>and</strong> fruit<br />

production is economically viable on very small tracts of l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the large fruit market<strong>in</strong>g<br />

organisations - Outspan <strong>and</strong> Unifruco - are <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> assist<strong>in</strong>g small farmers produc<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

high quality fruit that is required for export. In the citrus <strong>in</strong>dustry, most of the oranges <strong>and</strong><br />

grapefruit produced by black farmers orig<strong>in</strong>ates from former bantustan development<br />

schemes which have been transformed to allow <strong>in</strong>dividual control <strong>and</strong> cultivation of crops.<br />

Although <strong>in</strong>comes vary widely, on one scheme <strong>in</strong> the Northern Prov<strong>in</strong>ce some farmers are<br />

earn<strong>in</strong>g upwards of R100,000 per year, an enormous sum compared to average <strong>rural</strong> <strong>in</strong>comes<br />

<strong>in</strong> South Africa. The apparent success of schemes like these must be set aga<strong>in</strong>st the<br />

enormous costs of establish<strong>in</strong>g small scale fruit farm<strong>in</strong>g schemes. Establish<strong>in</strong>g citrus - which<br />

<strong>in</strong>volves prepar<strong>in</strong>g the l<strong>and</strong>, purchas<strong>in</strong>g trees <strong>and</strong> construct<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>frastructure for irrigation<br />

- is over R14,000 per hectare. This figure does not take <strong>in</strong>to consideration the <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

high cost of l<strong>and</strong> with access to water (van der Riet <strong>and</strong> Darroch 1993). Returns on<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment are typically only realised after five years <strong>and</strong> profits are earned only after 7 to 8<br />

depend<strong>in</strong>g on the proportion of the crop exported. The considerable costs of establish<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

fruit farm expla<strong>in</strong>s why Outspan is prepared to assist emerg<strong>in</strong>g farmers on former bantustan<br />

schemes where the <strong>in</strong>frastructure for irrigation farm<strong>in</strong>g is already <strong>in</strong> place. The result is that<br />

there are probably less than 100 citrus small scale black citrus farmers <strong>in</strong> the country. Large<br />

establishment costs also account for the current <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> equity schemes as a way of<br />

empower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rural</strong> workers <strong>in</strong> high value export <strong>agriculture</strong>. The obstacles to small farmers <strong>in</strong><br />

high value food exports is also apparent <strong>in</strong> other contexts. In Chile, where the<br />

transformation of farm<strong>in</strong>g towards exports has been extremely successful, l<strong>and</strong> concentration<br />

has occurred <strong>and</strong> smallholders have been marg<strong>in</strong>alised from the benefits of the export boom<br />

(Jaffee 1993).<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, Gear’s emphasis on small scale farm<strong>in</strong>g must be set aga<strong>in</strong>st its potential for<br />

alleviat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> eradicat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong>. There are two issues which suggest that emerg<strong>in</strong>g<br />

farmers cannot be the only solution to <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong>. The first was referred to earlier <strong>in</strong> the<br />

paper: recent <strong>poverty</strong> studies <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>rural</strong> Africans who are able to earn an <strong>in</strong>come<br />

from <strong>agriculture</strong> also earn wages <strong>in</strong> the primary labour market. The poorest <strong>rural</strong> households,<br />

<strong>in</strong> contrast, are unable to earn any <strong>in</strong>come whatsoever from <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>and</strong> use what is<br />

produced on the l<strong>and</strong> for personal consumption. A <strong>rural</strong> l<strong>and</strong> reform programme that is<br />

aimed at <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the efficiency of ‘emerg<strong>in</strong>g farmers’ is unlikely to reach the poorest<br />

households <strong>and</strong> is much more likely to assist farmers who are already earn<strong>in</strong>g part of their<br />

<strong>in</strong>come from farm<strong>in</strong>g. In other words, a small scale farm<strong>in</strong>g campaign is less likely to assist<br />

the poorest <strong>rural</strong> households <strong>and</strong> will probably <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>rural</strong> differentiation. The second<br />

issue is that even if a small farmer scheme were successful <strong>in</strong> target<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>rural</strong> poor, it is<br />

doubtful that enough farmers could be targeted to have a mean<strong>in</strong>gful impact on <strong>rural</strong><br />

15


<strong>poverty</strong>. Current estimates suggest that there are about 11 million poor people <strong>in</strong> the <strong>rural</strong><br />

areas. A l<strong>and</strong> reform scheme that was successful <strong>in</strong> creat<strong>in</strong>g 50,000 additional new small scale<br />

farmers would, however, “not have a major impact on the millions of <strong>rural</strong> households who<br />

have depended on wage <strong>in</strong>comes <strong>in</strong> order to survive” (St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g et al 1996, 262). Small scale<br />

farm<strong>in</strong>g, as the lynch-p<strong>in</strong> to l<strong>and</strong> reform, thus faces two overwhelm<strong>in</strong>g challenges: first, it is<br />

not likely to benefit from a neo-liberal macroeconomic environment <strong>and</strong> second, those<br />

farmers who are successful will not be numerous enough to have a significant impact on <strong>rural</strong><br />

<strong>poverty</strong>.<br />

Conclusion<br />

In the various macroeconomic scenarios discussed <strong>in</strong> this paper, <strong>agriculture</strong> is given a<br />

different role <strong>in</strong> growth <strong>and</strong> <strong>rural</strong> job creation. For the World Bank, the solution lies <strong>in</strong><br />

transferr<strong>in</strong>g resources to a more efficient <strong>and</strong> employment <strong>in</strong>tensive class of black emerg<strong>in</strong>g<br />

farmers. The Merg <strong>and</strong> ILO <strong>strategies</strong> stress the importance of <strong>agriculture</strong>’s role <strong>in</strong> job<br />

creation <strong>and</strong> its dynamic l<strong>in</strong>kages with other sectors of the economy. While these visions are<br />

very different, both rest on an <strong>in</strong>terventionist state which is prepared to exp<strong>and</strong> fiscal<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g for growth <strong>and</strong> employment. Gear’s message is very different. while it also sees<br />

smallholders as be<strong>in</strong>g key to the problem of <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong>, it is based on limited state<br />

<strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>and</strong> sees the private sector tak<strong>in</strong>g the lead <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment, growth <strong>and</strong> job<br />

creation. While Gear is silent on the role of commercial <strong>agriculture</strong>, its emphasis on export<br />

promotion is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with those sectors of <strong>agriculture</strong> that are already exp<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g rapidly. The<br />

success of <strong>rural</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation for wage workers <strong>in</strong> this sector depends on improv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

conditions through equity schemes <strong>and</strong> union organisation. Unfortunately, both of these are<br />

<strong>in</strong> a sense voluntary: equity schemes depend on workers <strong>and</strong> owners agree<strong>in</strong>g to jo<strong>in</strong>t<br />

ownership <strong>and</strong> unions have been most successful on farms where owners have agreed to the<br />

organisation of the workforce. Gear’s emphasis on smallholders is highly problematic given<br />

the equal or greater emphasis it places on fiscal austerity <strong>and</strong> an open economy. Local <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>ternational evidence suggests that smallholders do not fare well <strong>in</strong> a neoliberal environment<br />

<strong>and</strong> that when they do, it is through state support.<br />

The differences between the various macroeconomic <strong>strategies</strong> should not detract from<br />

the deeply political choice that been made <strong>in</strong> South Africa. The Merg <strong>and</strong> ILO have called<br />

for a radical <strong>and</strong> immediate solution to solve <strong>poverty</strong>, undoubtedly the country’s most<br />

profound problem. Informed by the Wash<strong>in</strong>gton consensus, Gear takes the conservative<br />

road. It rema<strong>in</strong>s to be seen whether this choice will underm<strong>in</strong>e the ‘fragile social fabric so<br />

carefully nurtured’ <strong>in</strong> the 1990s.<br />

16<br />

Policy recommendations <strong>and</strong> future research priorities<br />

This section explores a series of policy options. It does not attempt to provide an<br />

exhaustive set of options, but <strong>in</strong>stead considers a set of policy priorities that emerge from the<br />

project.<br />

• State support to smallholder farmers: GEAR makes a strong case for be<strong>in</strong>g an<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegrated strategy. In terms of its approach to small scale farm<strong>in</strong>g, however, it lacks<br />

<strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>in</strong> that it does not consider the broader implications of its strategy for<br />

smallholders. The report has shown how the liberalisation of <strong>agriculture</strong> often affects<br />

resource poor farmers more than those with greater resources <strong>and</strong> those who have<br />

benefited from policies <strong>in</strong> the past. Local predictions <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational case studies


suggest that smallholders are the first to suffer under a ‘freer’ trade regime. In Mexico,<br />

the implementation of NAFTA has disadvantaged small maize farmers to the extent that<br />

policymakers are recommend<strong>in</strong>g that the state assist farmers directly by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g yields<br />

or by help<strong>in</strong>g farmers to shift to higher value cash crops. A similar situation is likely <strong>in</strong><br />

South Africa, especially given the US’s <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> penetrat<strong>in</strong>g the local market with highly<br />

subsidised gra<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> oilseed exports. The state <strong>and</strong> the Department of Agriculture <strong>and</strong><br />

L<strong>and</strong> Affairs needs to be prepared for this chang<strong>in</strong>g environment <strong>and</strong> must be prepared<br />

to support small scale farmers more extensively <strong>and</strong> on a longer term than envisaged <strong>in</strong><br />

GEAR. Further research is required on what the impact of GEAR will be on small scale<br />

farmers (both men <strong>and</strong> women) <strong>in</strong> different parts of the country as well as the<br />

formulation of the most appropriate response from the Department of L<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Agriculture.<br />

• Agribus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong> export opportunities for small scale farmers: It was noted <strong>in</strong> the<br />

report that there are significant obstacles to small scale farmers enter<strong>in</strong>g the export<br />

market (especially citrus <strong>and</strong> deciduous fruit). The ma<strong>in</strong> constra<strong>in</strong>ts are that the start-up<br />

costs are too high <strong>and</strong> that <strong>in</strong>come generation is not immediate. Equity schemes are an<br />

important way for farm workers to participate more fully <strong>in</strong> the export market. However,<br />

there are other opportunities <strong>and</strong> large agribus<strong>in</strong>ess market<strong>in</strong>g organisations like Outspan<br />

<strong>and</strong> Unifruco must be encouraged to further exp<strong>and</strong> their <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> redistribution.<br />

• L<strong>in</strong>kages: Agriculture’s contribution to the rest of the economy is through its backward<br />

<strong>and</strong> forward l<strong>in</strong>kages. There is, nevertheless, some debate on the effectiveness of l<strong>in</strong>kages<br />

<strong>in</strong> practice <strong>and</strong> especially on their ‘spatiality’ (Harriss, 1987; Hart, 1989). The data on<br />

South Africa is also dated <strong>and</strong> static <strong>in</strong> that it has not exam<strong>in</strong>ed how these l<strong>in</strong>kages might<br />

have changed s<strong>in</strong>ce the mid-1980s. Moreover, there is no research on where the benefits<br />

of the l<strong>in</strong>kages occur: do they rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong> areas or is the primary impact of the<br />

l<strong>in</strong>kages <strong>in</strong> urban areas? This question has crucial implications for agricultural policy <strong>and</strong><br />

its potential contribution to redistribution <strong>and</strong> growth <strong>and</strong> must be an area of future<br />

research.<br />

• Employment <strong>and</strong> equity schemes: One of the crucial f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of the various <strong>poverty</strong><br />

surveys is the importance of wage work <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> for the <strong>rural</strong> poor. The problem is<br />

that wages <strong>and</strong> conditions of employment are appall<strong>in</strong>g. Ways must be found of<br />

improv<strong>in</strong>g conditions for this sector as it will have a direct impact on the poorest <strong>rural</strong><br />

households.<br />

17<br />

References<br />

Acevedo, C., Barry, D., Rosa, H. 1995. El Salvador’s agricultural sector: macroeconomic<br />

policy, agrarian change <strong>and</strong> the environment. World Development 23(12): 2153-2172.<br />

Adelzadeh, A. 1996a. From the RDP to GEAR: the gradual embrac<strong>in</strong>g of neo-liberalism <strong>in</strong><br />

economic policy. Transformation 30: 1-17.<br />

Adelzadeh, A 1996b. Growth <strong>and</strong> Development: Labour <strong>and</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess perspectives on<br />

economic development. In Aga<strong>in</strong>st the Current: Labour <strong>and</strong> Economic Policy <strong>in</strong> South<br />

Africa, ed. J. Bask<strong>in</strong>, 41-59. Johannesburg: Ravan Press.<br />

Adelzadeh, A. <strong>and</strong> Padayachee, V. 1994. The RDP White Paper: the reconstruction of a<br />

development vision? Transformation 25:1-17.<br />

Agrifutura 1996. Agrifutura. University of Stellenbosch.


Bell, T. 1996. Creat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rural</strong> livelihoods <strong>in</strong> the Western Cape: macroeconomic, trade related<br />

<strong>and</strong> policy factors. In Labour <strong>and</strong> Livelihoods <strong>in</strong> Rural South Africa, Vol 1: Western Cape,<br />

eds. M. Lipton, M. de Klerk, <strong>and</strong> M. Lipton, pages. London: IPSA.<br />

Bromberger, N. <strong>and</strong> Antonie, F. 1993: Black small farmers <strong>in</strong> the homel<strong>and</strong>s: economic<br />

prospects <strong>and</strong> policies, In State <strong>and</strong> Market <strong>in</strong> <strong>post</strong>-apartheid South Africa, eds. M. Lipton<br />

<strong>and</strong> C. Simk<strong>in</strong>s, 409-449. Boulder: Westview Press.<br />

Carter, M. <strong>and</strong> Barham, B.L. 1996. Level play<strong>in</strong>g fields <strong>and</strong> laissez faire: <strong>post</strong>liberal<br />

development strategy <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>egalitarian economies. World Development 24(7):1133-1149.<br />

Carvalho, J.L. 1991. Agriculture, <strong>in</strong>dustrialization <strong>and</strong> the macroeconomic environment <strong>in</strong><br />

Brazil. Food Policy 2:48-56.<br />

Clapp, J.A. 1993. Interpret<strong>in</strong>g agricultural perfomance <strong>in</strong> Guniea under structural adjusment.<br />

Canadian Journal of African Studies 27(2):173-195.<br />

Cooper, D. 1991: Agriculture <strong>in</strong> the bantustans: towards development policies, <strong>in</strong> A Harvest of<br />

Discontent: the L<strong>and</strong> Question <strong>in</strong> South Africa, ed. M. de Klerk (ed), 239-258. Cape Town:<br />

Idasa.<br />

de Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E. <strong>and</strong> Gordillo de Anda, G. 1995. NAFTA <strong>and</strong> Mexico’s maize<br />

producers. World Development 23(8): 1349-1362.<br />

de Klerk, M. 1984. Seasons that will never return: the impact of farm mechanization on<br />

employment, <strong>in</strong>comes <strong>and</strong> population distribution <strong>in</strong> the Western Transvaal. Journal of<br />

Southern African Studies 11:84-105.<br />

de Klerk, M. 1996: Susta<strong>in</strong>able livelihood creation potential of small scale horticulture <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Western Cape. In Labour <strong>and</strong> Livelihoods <strong>in</strong> Rural South Africa, Vol 1: Western Cape, eds.<br />

M. Lipton, M. de Klerk, <strong>and</strong> M. Lipton, 201-244. London: IPSA.<br />

De Wet, C. 1990. The socio-economic impact of development schemes <strong>in</strong> the ‘homel<strong>and</strong>s’ of<br />

South Africa. South African Journal of Science 86:440-447.<br />

Dixie, G. 1995. Southern Africa citrus case study, Report for World Bank Southern Africa<br />

Agriculture <strong>and</strong> Environmental Group, Uxbride, U.K.<br />

Dolny, H. 1993. Economic growth, agricultural reform <strong>and</strong> the alleviation of <strong>poverty</strong>. South<br />

African Journal of Economics 12(3):205-237.<br />

Due, J.M. <strong>and</strong> Gladw<strong>in</strong>, C.H. 1991. Impacts of structural adjustment programs on African<br />

women farmers <strong>and</strong> female-headed households. American Agricultural Economics Journal<br />

73(5):1431-1439.<br />

Eckert, J.B., Hamman, J.N. <strong>and</strong> Lombard, J.P. 1996. Perceiv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> new future: empower<strong>in</strong>g<br />

farm workers through equity shar<strong>in</strong>g. Development Southern Africa 13:693-712.<br />

Eidelberg, P.G. 1997. The tripartite alliance on the even of a new millenium, Paper presented<br />

at Institute of Advanced Social Research, # 413, University of the Witwatersr<strong>and</strong>,<br />

Johannesburg.<br />

Fallon, P. <strong>and</strong> Pereira de Silva, L.A. 1994. South Africa: Economic Performance <strong>and</strong> Policies,<br />

World Bank Southern Africa Department, Discussion Paper 7, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.<br />

Faux, C.S. 1990. Input-output analysis of employment <strong>in</strong> agribus<strong>in</strong>ess, M.B.A. thesis,<br />

University of the Witwatersr<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Gibson, B. <strong>and</strong> van Seventer, D.E. 1996. Towards a growth strategy for the South African<br />

economy, Development Southern Africa 13:511-537.<br />

Harriss, B. 1987. Regional growth l<strong>in</strong>kages from <strong>agriculture</strong>. Journal of Development Studies<br />

23(2):266-289.<br />

Hart, G. 1989. The growth l<strong>in</strong>kages controversy: some lessons from the Muda case. Journal of<br />

Development Studies 25(1):571-575.<br />

Hart, G. 1994. The new economic policy <strong>and</strong> redistribution <strong>in</strong> Malaysia: a model for <strong>post</strong>apartheid<br />

South Africa. Transformation 23:44-59.<br />

Jaffee, S. 1993. Export<strong>in</strong>g high value food commodities: some success stories from<br />

develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, World Bank Discussion Paper 198, World Bank, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton.<br />

18


Kapl<strong>in</strong>sky, R. 1994. ‘Economic restructur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> South Africa: the debate cont<strong>in</strong>ues’: a<br />

response. Journal of Southern African Studies 20(4):533-537.<br />

Keet, D. 1996. The European Union’s proposed free trade agreement with South Africa: the<br />

implications <strong>and</strong> some counter-proposals. Development Southern Africa 13:555-566.<br />

Kirsten, J.F., van Rooyen, J. <strong>and</strong> Ngqangweni, S. 1996. Progress with different l<strong>and</strong> reform<br />

options <strong>in</strong> South Africa. Agrekon 35(4):218-223.<br />

L<strong>in</strong>desay, C. 1991. Economic <strong>and</strong> socio-political impacts of ra<strong>in</strong>fall variations, M.B.A Thesis,<br />

University of the Witwatersr<strong>and</strong>, Johannesburg.<br />

Lipton, M. 1996. Rural reforms <strong>and</strong> <strong>rural</strong> livelihoods: the contexts of <strong>in</strong>ternational experience,<br />

In Labour <strong>and</strong> Livelihoods <strong>in</strong> Rural South Africa, Vol 1: Western Cape, eds. M. Lipton, M.<br />

de Klerk, <strong>and</strong> M. Lipton, 1-49. London: IPSA.<br />

Mackenzie, C. 1996. Farm worker equity model mechanism to broaden the ownership base <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>, Paper presented at L<strong>and</strong> Redistribution Conference, October 1993,<br />

LAPC.<br />

Mackenzie, F. 1993. Explor<strong>in</strong>g the connections: structural adjustment, gender <strong>and</strong> the<br />

environment. Geoforum 24(1):71-87.<br />

Marcus, T. 1989. Modernis<strong>in</strong>g Super-Exploitation: Restructur<strong>in</strong>g Agriculture <strong>in</strong> South Africa. London:<br />

Zed.<br />

Mather, C. 1993. The anatomy of a <strong>rural</strong> strike: power <strong>and</strong> space <strong>in</strong> the eastern Transvaal<br />

lowveld. Canadian Journal of African Studies 27(3):424-439.<br />

May, J. 1996. Experience <strong>and</strong> perceptions of <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> South Africa, Third Draft, Data<br />

Research Africa, Durban.<br />

May, J., Carter, G. <strong>and</strong> Posel, D. 1995: The composition <strong>and</strong> persistence of <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>rural</strong><br />

South Africa, LAPC policy paper, 15, Johannesburg.<br />

McIntosh, A. <strong>and</strong> Vaughan, A. 1995. State-centred commercial smallholder development:<br />

haves <strong>and</strong> haves-nots <strong>in</strong> KaNgwane. Development Southern Africa 12:113-121.<br />

Mehra, R. 1991. Can structural adjustment work for women farmers. American Agricultural<br />

Economics Association 73(5):1440-1447.<br />

Merg, 1993: Mak<strong>in</strong>g Democracy Work: A Framework for <strong>Macroeconomic</strong> Development Policy <strong>in</strong> South<br />

Africa. Oxford University: Cape Town.<br />

Moolman, H. <strong>and</strong> Lambrechts, J. 1996. Physical l<strong>and</strong> use resources affect<strong>in</strong>g the long term<br />

environmental susta<strong>in</strong>ability of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> the Western Cape. In Labour <strong>and</strong><br />

Livelihoods <strong>in</strong> Rural South Africa, Vol 1: Western Cape, eds. M. Lipton, M. de Klerk, <strong>and</strong><br />

M. Lipton, 117-156. London: IPSA.<br />

Morales, J.A. 1991. Structural adjustment <strong>and</strong> peasant <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> Bolivia. Food Policy<br />

16(1):58-66.<br />

Nattrass, N. 1994. Economic restructur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> South Africa: the debate cont<strong>in</strong>ues. Journal of<br />

Southern African Studies 20(4):517-531.<br />

Nattrass, N. 1996. Gambl<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>in</strong>vestment. Transformation 30:25-45.<br />

Nel, P., van Rooyen, J. <strong>and</strong> Ngqangweni, S. 1995. Farmworker participation schemes:<br />

conditions for success. Agrekon 34(4):183-189.<br />

Phillips-Howard, K. <strong>and</strong> Porter, G. 1996. Small-scale irrigation <strong>and</strong> the reconstruction <strong>and</strong><br />

development of Transkei, South Africa. Area 28(3):373-383.<br />

Porter, G. <strong>and</strong> Phillips-Howard, K. 1996. Tensions <strong>and</strong> transformation <strong>in</strong> a tea enterprise:<br />

Transkei, South Africa. The Geographical Journal 162(3):187-194.<br />

Pretorius, C.J. <strong>and</strong> Smal, M.M. 1992. Notes on the macro-economic effects of the drought,<br />

Quarterly Bullet<strong>in</strong> of the Reserve Bank, June, 1992, 31-38.<br />

RDP, 1996. A Profile Of Poverty In South Africa. Pretoria: Reconstruction <strong>and</strong> Development<br />

Programme.<br />

Republic of South Africa, 1996. Growth, Employment <strong>and</strong> Redistribution: A <strong>Macroeconomic</strong> Strategy,<br />

Pretoria: Department of F<strong>in</strong>ance.<br />

Rix, S. 1996. A nightmare <strong>and</strong> a near miss. South African Labour Bullet<strong>in</strong> 20(3):30-35.<br />

19


Rustomjee, Z. 1993: Is there a manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>agriculture</strong> complex? unpublished paper.<br />

Sahn, D.E. <strong>and</strong> Arulpragasam, J. 1991. The stagnation of smallholder <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> Malawi: a<br />

decade of structural adjustment. Food Policy 16(3):219-234.<br />

Sender, J. 1993. Rural <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> l<strong>and</strong> redistribution: some macroeconomic issues, Paper<br />

presented at L<strong>and</strong> Redistribution Conference, October 1993, LAPC.<br />

Sender, J. 1994. Economic restructur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> South Africa: reactionary rhetoric prevails. Journal<br />

of Southern African Studies 20(4):539-543.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>gh, A. <strong>and</strong> Tabatabai, H. 1992. Agriculture <strong>and</strong> economic development <strong>in</strong> the 1990s: a new<br />

analytical <strong>and</strong> policy agenda. International Labour Review 131(4):405-430.<br />

St<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g, G., Sender, J. <strong>and</strong> Weeks, J. 1996. Restructur<strong>in</strong>g the South African Labour Market.<br />

Geneva: International Labour Office.<br />

Taylor, L. 1997: Editorial: the revival of the liberal creed - the IMF <strong>and</strong> the World Bank <strong>in</strong> a<br />

globalized economy. World Development 25(2):145-152.<br />

van der Riet, D.F. <strong>and</strong> Darroch, M. 1993. Impact of l<strong>and</strong> prices of export dem<strong>and</strong> for South<br />

African deciduous fruit: 1972-1992. Agrekon 32(4):247-251.<br />

van Rooyen, C.J., Fenyes, T.I. <strong>and</strong> van Zyl, J. 1987. A comparison of the contribution <strong>and</strong><br />

relative performance of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> Southern Africa, Development Southern Africa 4:58-<br />

75.<br />

Van Zyl, J. 1993. The last straw: drought <strong>and</strong> the economy. Indicator SA 10: 47-51.<br />

van Zyl, J. <strong>and</strong> V<strong>in</strong>k, N. 1988. Employment <strong>and</strong> growth <strong>in</strong> South Africa: an agricultural<br />

perspective, Development Southern Africa, 5:12-29.<br />

van Zyl, J., van der Vyver, A. <strong>and</strong> Groenewald, J.A. 1988. The <strong>in</strong>fluence of drought <strong>and</strong><br />

general economic effects on <strong>agriculture</strong>: a macro-analysis, Agrekon 26(1):8-12.<br />

Vaughan, A. <strong>and</strong> McIntosh, A. 1993. State <strong>and</strong> capital <strong>in</strong> the regeneration of a South African<br />

peasantry. Canadian Journal of African Studies 27(3):439-455.<br />

Vogel, C. 1994: Consequences of droughts <strong>in</strong> Southern Africa, 1960-1992, Unpublished PhD<br />

thesis, University of the Witwatersr<strong>and</strong>, Johannesburg.<br />

Williams, G. 1996. Sett<strong>in</strong>g the agenda: a critique of the World Bank’s <strong>rural</strong> restructur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

programme for South Africa. Journal of Southern African Studies 22(1):139-166.<br />

World Bank, 1994. South African Agriculture: Structure, Performance <strong>and</strong> Options for the<br />

Future, Discussion Paper 6, World Bank Southern Africa Department, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton,<br />

DC.<br />

20

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!