24.07.2014 Views

Governance, Growth, and Development Decision-making - School of ...

Governance, Growth, and Development Decision-making - School of ...

Governance, Growth, and Development Decision-making - School of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

tutional prerequisites <strong>and</strong> one where they have been remarkably effective.<br />

A similar kind <strong>of</strong> institutionally-rich thinking has developed<br />

in a few other areas as well—as in education policy <strong>and</strong> in telecom<br />

regulation. But in many other areas, such thinking is either quite<br />

naïve or non-existent. I would cite trade policy <strong>and</strong> industrial policy<br />

as examples <strong>of</strong> the first <strong>and</strong> second categories, respectively. In trade<br />

policy, the long-st<strong>and</strong>ing advocacy by external advisors <strong>of</strong> uniform<br />

tariff rules (or <strong>of</strong> external commitments) is typically motivated by<br />

very poorly articulated political <strong>and</strong> institutional priors—basically<br />

lots <strong>of</strong> arm-waving. And in industrial policy, the dominant view—<br />

held essentially on a priori grounds—seems to be that the requisite<br />

institutional arrangement are impossible to design <strong>and</strong> implement,<br />

even when such a policy is desirable in principle.<br />

As the example <strong>of</strong> central banking shows, economists have a lot<br />

to contribute to thinking about such issues in specific policy areas.<br />

Their underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the substantive issues, their pr<strong>of</strong>essional<br />

obsession with incentives, <strong>and</strong> their eye for the unanticipated consequences<br />

give them a natural advantage in designing institutional<br />

arrangements to further the objectives in question while minimizing<br />

behavioral distortions. A certain amount <strong>of</strong> local knowledge<br />

is clearly indispensable here. Economists need to underst<strong>and</strong> the<br />

local context well enough to recognize the limits on the range <strong>of</strong><br />

possibilities <strong>and</strong> to anticipate the likely obstacles. But doing this in<br />

the context <strong>of</strong> relaxing a constraint in a particular policy area—be<br />

it monetary policy, trade policy, industrial policy, or education<br />

policy—seems to be me to be an order <strong>of</strong> magnitude simpler than<br />

designing wholesale legal reform or mounting an effective anti-corruption<br />

drive across the board. And as I have argued above, it is also<br />

more effective where growth is concerned.<br />

4. Avoiding the Best-practices Trap<br />

Designing appropriate institutional arrangements requires local<br />

knowledge <strong>and</strong> creativity. What works in one setting is unlikely to<br />

work in another. In a second-best, (i.e., real) world, the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

Dani Rodrik 21

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!